Enquiries Into Intellectual Property`s Economic Impact

Transcription

Enquiries Into Intellectual Property`s Economic Impact
Enquiries Into Intellectual
Property’s Economic Impact
Cover image: The cover depicts a person holding a tablet that displays an infra-red image of a house.
The innovations in the tablet are protected by a variety of intellectual property rights, including
patents, design rights, and copyrights, all of which are discussed in this report.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY’S
ECONOMIC IMPACT
2 | TOC
TABLE OF CONTENTS
FOREWORD................................................................................................................................................... 5
CHAPTER 1. SYNTHESIS ........................................................................................................................... 7
Executive Summary......................................................................................................................................... 8
Key challenges ................................................................................................................................................ 8
Introduction: The Context and Motivation for Knowledge-based Capital Phase 2 ....................................... 11
Aims of Phase 2/IP ........................................................................................................................................ 26
Key Findings ................................................................................................................................................. 26
Other Policy Challenges in Need of Further Study ....................................................................................... 60
Conclusion ..................................................................................................................................................... 62
ANNEX ......................................................................................................................................................... 63
CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS .... 85
Abstract ......................................................................................................................................................... 86
Executive Summary....................................................................................................................................... 87
Introduction ................................................................................................................................................... 88
Patent scope ................................................................................................................................................... 90
Patent family size .......................................................................................................................................... 92
Grant lag ........................................................................................................................................................ 94
Backward citations ........................................................................................................................................ 96
Citations to non-patent literature (NPL) ........................................................................................................ 98
Claims .......................................................................................................................................................... 100
Forward citations ......................................................................................................................................... 103
Breakthrough inventions ............................................................................................................................. 107
Generality index .......................................................................................................................................... 109
Originality index.......................................................................................................................................... 111
Radicalness index ........................................................................................................................................ 113
Patent renewal ............................................................................................................................................. 115
Patent value: composite index ..................................................................................................................... 117
ANNEX ....................................................................................................................................................... 122
CHAPTER 3. APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS ................................... 127
Abstract ....................................................................................................................................................... 128
Executive Summary..................................................................................................................................... 129
Introduction ................................................................................................................................................. 130
The International Framework and the Definition of Trade Secrets ............................................................. 130
Literature Review ........................................................................................................................................ 133
Method......................................................................................................................................................... 137
Survey of Legal Provisions and Practices ................................................................................................... 138
Trade Secret Protection Index ..................................................................................................................... 143
Conclusions ................................................................................................................................................. 145
ANNEXES .................................................................................................................................................. 172
CHAPTER 4. AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF
PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS ................................................................................................... 173
Abstract ....................................................................................................................................................... 174
Executive Summary..................................................................................................................................... 175
Introduction ................................................................................................................................................. 175
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
3 | TOC
Overview: International Framework for Protection of Trade Secrets ......................................................... 176
Qualitative Assessment ............................................................................................................................... 177
Trade Secrets Protection Index .................................................................................................................... 180
Quantitative Assessment ............................................................................................................................. 182
Conclusions ................................................................................................................................................. 184
ANNEX ....................................................................................................................................................... 200
CHAPTER 5. COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES ....................................... 209
Executive Summary..................................................................................................................................... 210
The technological revolution and the economic performance of copyright-intensive industries ................ 210
Evolving legal frameworks and the surrounding debates ............................................................................ 213
Introduction and Background ...................................................................................................................... 216
Scope of the chapter .................................................................................................................................... 216
Copyright - An Economic Perspective - Definitions and scope .................................................................. 217
Economic rationale for copyrights .............................................................................................................. 218
Copyright-intensive industries..................................................................................................................... 219
Copyright and the Internet Revolution - The changing landscape .............................................................. 220
Focus on legal frameworks .......................................................................................................................... 228
Country Studies ........................................................................................................................................... 232
Australia ...................................................................................................................................................... 232
Canada ......................................................................................................................................................... 236
Chile ............................................................................................................................................................ 244
Egypt ........................................................................................................................................................... 246
The European Union ................................................................................................................................... 253
Italy.............................................................................................................................................................. 256
Japan ............................................................................................................................................................ 263
Korea ........................................................................................................................................................... 267
Poland .......................................................................................................................................................... 282
Switzerland .................................................................................................................................................. 287
The United Kingdom ................................................................................................................................... 291
The United States ........................................................................................................................................ 295
ANNEX. ...................................................................................................................................................... 304
CHAPTER 6. DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC
PERFORMANCE ....................................................................................................................................... 323
Introduction ................................................................................................................................................. 324
Protecting design ......................................................................................................................................... 328
Design IP complementarities ....................................................................................................................... 338
Trends in design outcomes, with a focus on registered designs .................................................................. 341
Measures of design inputs ........................................................................................................................... 354
Measurement of design outputs ................................................................................................................... 358
Conclusion ................................................................................................................................................... 363
CHAPTER 7. LEGAL ASPECTS OF OPEN ACCESS TO PUBLICLY FUNDED RESEARCH .......... 373
Executive Summary..................................................................................................................................... 374
Introduction ................................................................................................................................................. 376
Scientific output and Intellectual property protection ................................................................................. 378
National legislative framework ................................................................................................................... 380
Open Access Policies .................................................................................................................................. 398
Unresolved Issues ........................................................................................................................................ 401
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
4 | TOC
CHAPTER 8. SUMMARY OF THE EXPERT WORKSHOP, “SOCIETY’S GAIN FROM THE
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY EXCHANGE” ......................................................................................... 415
Executive Summary..................................................................................................................................... 416
General Themes ........................................................................................................................................... 416
Patents ......................................................................................................................................................... 418
Trade Secrets ............................................................................................................................................... 419
Copyright ..................................................................................................................................................... 419
CHAPTER 9. IP-BASED FINANCING OF INNOVATIVE FIRMS ....................................................... 457
Introduction ................................................................................................................................................. 458
Innovation financing and intellectual property ............................................................................................ 458
IP-based finance: developments and barriers .............................................................................................. 461
Policies for IP-based finance ....................................................................................................................... 466
Conclusions ................................................................................................................................................. 470
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
5 | FOREWORD
FOREWORD
“Enquiries into Intellectual Property’s Economic Impact” is a result of the combined expertise and
effort of six parts of the OECD (Consumer Policy, Digital Economy, Science & Technology, Industry and
Entrepreneurship, Tax Policy, and Trade). A component of the multidisciplinary OECD Project New
Sources of Growth: Knowledge-based Capital, Phase 2, this report has its roots in an earlier horizontal
project called The Innovation Strategy, delivered in 2010 and currently being updated. That report
identifies ways in which governments can promote innovation to capitalise on its power to drive
productivity and income growth forward. In the midst of that work, the economy entered into its worst
slowdown in 70 years, leading to a follow-on project, New Sources of Growth: Knowledge-based Capital,
Phase 1, aimed at identifying new drivers of growth. Building on seminal work from the staff of the United
States Federal Reserve Board 1, this study identified a new class of capital assets – “knowledge-based
capital” (KBC) such as R&D, design, software, data and intellectual property like patents and copyright –
which are difficult to measure but critical strategic investments for retaining and building competitiveness.
As KBC becomes recognised as a driver of new sources of growth, and as the ownership of KBC becomes
commonplace across all sectors of the economy, a number of policy challenges emerge, as analysed in
Phase 1.
Amongst these are policies to nurture and protect intellectual property (IP). Hereto now, in some
countries IP mainly affected specific sectors like pharmaceuticals and artistic content. Mobile phone wars,
for example, are a new development, and a mobile phone may have as many as 3 000 different patents. In
addition, the development of technologies like digitisation and the Internet has brought consumers into
more direct and frequent contact with copyright laws than ever before by making it far easier, faster, and
cheaper to create, duplicate, and disseminate content. The aim of this second phase of work is to examine
how those developments have interacted with IP and to develop analytical tools and collect information
that will facilitate insights and analysis. The goal is to recognise IP’s growing importance and ensure that it
is as valuable and helpful as it can be to OECD economies. Now, more than ever, policy makers need to
harness drivers of growth like the creativity and ideas contained in intellectual property to stimulate
economic growth and foster social well-being.
Given the multidisciplinary nature of the work on KBC and intellectual property, the chapters of this
report were discussed and declassified by a variety of OECD Committees, including the Digital Economy
Policy Committee, the Committee for Scientific and Technological Policy, the Committee on Industry,
Innovation and Entrepreneurship, and the Trade Committee. The content and comments contributed by the
delegates to these OECD official bodies are gratefully acknowledged.
Many OECD staff contributed to this report. Jeremy West wrote Chapter 1 (Synthesis). Chapter 2
(Measuring the Technological and Economic Value of Patents) was written by Mariagrazia Squicciarini,
Hélène Dernis, and Chiara Criscuolo. Chapters 3 and 4 (Approaches to the Protection of Trade Secrets and
An Empirical Assessment of Protection for Trade Secrets) were authored by Douglas Lippoldt and Mark
Schultz. Piotr Stryszowski wrote Chapter 5 (Copyright in the Digital Era). Chapter 6 (Design and Design
Frameworks: Investment in KBC and Economic Performance) was written by Christopher Tucci and Tilo
Peters with comments from Mariagrazia Squicciarini. Lucie Guibault and Thomas Margoni wrote Chapter
7 (Legal Aspects of Open Access to Publicly Funded Research) with guidance from Mario Cervantes and
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
6 | FOREWORD
Giulia Ajmone-Marsan. Niamh Dunne was the Rapporteur for the expert workshop and wrote Chapter 8
(Summary of the Expert Workshop). Chapter 9 (IP-Based Financing) was authored by Marco Antonielli
with guidance from Jeremy West. The entire project benefited from Anne Carblanc’s guidance. Alistair
Nolan, who managed the KBC Phase 1 project, also provided valuable information and advice. Special
thanks to Sarah Ferguson, Helen Maguire, and Jane Warren-Peachey for all of their invaluable
administrative support, and to Kate Brooks for proofreading and creating the web page. The assistance of
Joshua Yeremiyew, who helped with several of the diagrams and charts in the synthesis chapter, is also
greatly appreciated.
This report also benefited from the advice of a panel of delegates drawn from the participating
committees. Many thanks to Maria Ludovica Agro, Heather Anderson, Suso Baleato, Maurizio Cerratti,
Tony Clayton, Dave Dupuis, Stephanie Eshelman, Gregory Garramone, Rita Goldstein, Roger Higginson,
Ali Karami-Ruiz, Konstantinos Komaitis, Thomas Nortvedt, Max Peterson, Filippos Pierros, Nicole
Primmer, Michel Sabbagh, and Scott Smith. Comments from Brian Kahin and Matt Schruers were very
informative, as well.
Finally, Walter Park kindly granted the OECD permission to use his patent rights index data. Peter
Goodridge graciously provided supplementary data on investment in tangible and intangible assets in the
United Kingdom.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
7 | SYNTHESIS
CHAPTER 1. SYNTHESIS
This chapter provides the rationale and context for Enquiries into Intellectual Property’s Economic Impact
and highlights its most significant findings. In doing so, the chapter presents the major themes of the
overall report, which are 1) the importance of various types of intellectual property as sources of growth
and innovation in today’s economies; and 2) the effects on IP systems and stakeholders of major
developments such as content digitisation, the growth of the Internet, and globalisation.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities or third
party. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and
Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
It should be noted that statistical data on Israeli patents and trademarks are supplied by the patent and trademark
offices of the relevant countries.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
8 | SYNTHESIS
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Key challenges
•
Copyright appears to be the type of IP that has been attracting business investment at the highest
growth rate and it is undergoing statutory review in many countries, yet there are fewer empirical
studies about copyright than about patents. Encouraging and enabling the collection and
availability of more data on copyright would facilitate data-driven copyright policy. In fact,
robust evidence on the use of IP rights generally and on their economic and social impacts is
essential for sound IP systems. Presently, however, relatively little concrete evidence is available
to support the common assumption that IP rights encourage greater innovation and creativity.
More economic evidence is needed.
•
At the same time, the copyright system could benefit from review and analysis with a view
towards clarifying its underlying principles, as well as clarifying the standards for delineating the
exclusive rights and exceptions to those rights that are informed by the principles. Such reviews
and analyses could make the use of copyrighted works more transparent, consistent, and
predictable.
•
Young innovative firms have the strongest track record for creating jobs, but it has become
harder for them to find financing. Making it easier to use IP (in particular patents and design
rights) to obtain financing would help some young firms to drive job growth and spur innovation.
•
To leverage the economic benefits of patents, take steps to improve the diffusion of patent
information after publication, consistent with international norms.
•
Initial work on trade secrets in this report suggests a link between trade secret protection and
innovation, pointing to an issue which merits continued study.
General points
•
Intellectual property rights are exclusive rights held by the owners of a variety of knowledgebased assets that qualify for legal protection under applicable IP laws. The main types of IP rights
are patents, copyrights, design rights, trademarks, and geographical indications. Trade secrets are
sometimes considered to be IP rights, too, though many countries do not expressly define them as
such.
•
IP rights support innovation by making it a more worthwhile investment and encouraging
knowledge diffusion. The economic rationale for IP rights is that it is in everyone’s long-term
interest for people and businesses that create knowledge to have well-defined, enforceable rights
to exclude third parties from appropriating their ideas, or the expression of their ideas, without
permission. Failing to put restrictions on appropriating others’ inventions and creations would
dilute the rewards for investing in innovation, thereby reducing the incentives for making such
investments. In addition, both i) disclosure requirements and time limits for exclusivity that are
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
9 | SYNTHESIS
built into IP laws, and ii) IP rights’ facilitation of licensing and other knowledge transfers,
contribute to knowledge diffusion and thus to innovation. 2
•
IP’s overall role in economies has evolved from a policy area that was mainly relevant to a
handful of industries to a force that influences a wide swath of demand and sectors.
Consequently, IP policy has become a more influential framework condition that affects not only
innovation, but trade, competition, taxes, consumer protection, and other areas.
•
Investment in IP-protected capital is growing faster than investment in tangible capital, and
salaries in IP-intensive sectors are higher than in non-IP-intensive sectors. The available evidence
on IP’s aggregate role also shows that IP’s economic importance has grown over time and that it
remained resilient during the recent recession.
•
The context in which IP operates has been changing substantially. IP frameworks and
stakeholders have been and continue to be affected by a number of developments, including the
rise of cloud computing, the growth of the Internet, digitisation, and globalisation. These have
created both new challenges for IP, including the facilitation of piracy and industrial espionage,
and new opportunities for it to stimulate inventions and creativity as well as to facilitate greater
access to information and creative works. For example, new business models and research tools
(based on, e.g., text/data mining, open access, and e-content) hold the promise of jobs, growth,
and greater knowledge diffusion.
•
IP-based financing deserves attention. Young firms contribute disproportionately to job
creation. Among the most important factors affecting their success is the ease of access to
financing. Capital is often relatively difficult for young firms to obtain because they do not have
long histories of consistently repaying loans and they tend to lack traditional collateral. But some
young firms have untapped resources in the form of IP, which – if it can be properly valued and if
markets for IP-based financing are functioning well – can be used to persuade lenders and
investors to provide financing. Indeed, a substantial body of empirical work has found that
young, high-growth firms with IP assets receive more funding than firms without IP.
Nevertheless, IP-based finance is significantly under-used, especially by SMEs that are most in
need of it. One reason is a lack of opportunities to sell IP in secondary markets. While open
source models may not be predicated on enforcement, in some countries a lack of effective IP
enforcement can be another barrier to obtaining financing. Policy makers are striving to support
IP markets in several countries. Generally, their efforts fall into two categories: i) supporting
greater transparency of IP ownership and transfer information via disclosure requirements or
measures to foster greater clarity in patent claims; and ii) creating new IP market infrastructures.
Another approach that governments can take is to help manage the risks associated with
collateralising IP. Government agencies and development banks can do that through risk-sharing
mechanisms.
Points about particular types of IP rights
•
IP rights involve more than just patents; copyright and trade secrets have a bigger role than
some might have thought. Indeed, they are the most economically significant forms of IP rights
in some respects, yet they have benefited from relatively less research, mainly because there is
much less data available on them than there is on patents. It is inherently difficult to obtain data
on trade secrets due to the fact that they lose their legal protection if they are made public;
however, more could be done to improve data availability with respect to copyright. One
possibility is to implement more measures designed to encourage voluntary copyright registration.
Other potential actions include funding research and surveys to estimate the benefits of more
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
10 | SYNTHESIS
registration, and changing the accounting rules that apply to creative industries to enable better
data collection. This should be done while bearing in mind that under the Berne Convention
registration is not mandatory.
•
Copyright’s performance excels in terms of the magnitude of investment it attracts, the growth
rate of that investment, and job growth. Therefore, to the extent that this synthesis chapter devotes
more space to copyright issues than to issues related to other types of IP rights, an important
reason is that copyright’s role in economies appears to be growing larger, faster. Note that, in
much of the world, copyright protects a significant amount of software investment – sometimes
more than in the rest of the ‘creative industries’. Furthermore, although the report discusses the
copyright intensive industries at some length, it is important to recognise that user generated
content is now also a significant source of entertainment and information.
•
Several governments have embarked on a review of their copyright laws to make sure they
remain fit for the digital age, with the aim of ensuring that their legal frameworks maintain
effective incentives for creators and all stakeholders in the value chain including intermediaries
and to consider whether certain aspects of the copyright regimes need to be adapted to the 21st
century. For example, such efforts have been undertaken in the United Kingdom, Ireland and
Australia. The ways in which copyrighted material is being created, disseminated, and used have
changed substantially due to digitisation and the Internet. As a result, a new dynamic amongst
stakeholder interests has emerged, which has fuelled a debate about the effects of copyright law
and particular provisions on the growth of a wide range of economic activities that depend upon
digital networks and products.
•
Evidence that patents stimulate innovation is mixed. Several surveys have shown that patents
are not considered to be very effective in protecting innovations outside a small number of
sectors. However, other reports indicate that growth in patent-intensive industries following the
2008-2009 recession outpaced growth in non-IP-intensive industries. In any event, studies still
have not definitively concluded that stronger, broader patent rights are necessarily resulting in
more innovation. Despite this mixed evidence, over the past 20 years or so patent rights have
generally become broader and stronger, and there has been a surge in the number of patents
granted.
•
Several ways to estimate the technological and economic value of patented inventions and
the impact they may have on subsequent technological developments are provided in this
Report, making it possible to shed more light on the patent-innovation relationship. The Report
proposes several indicators and illustrates what they can do with data from the European Patent
Office. The illustrative results show that: i) the average technological and economic value of
inventions protected by patents has eroded over time, at least through 2004, possibly reflecting
application backlogs as well as strategic behaviours like defensive patent filings; ii) patented
micro and nano technologies have the highest economic and technological value; and iii)
Australia, Canada, Norway, South Africa, and the United Kingdom are the countries with the
highest average technological and economic patent values.
•
Taking certain steps to improve disclosure and dissemination of the information contained
in patent applications could boost the impact that patented inventions have on subsequent
technological developments. This would more fully achieve a primary purpose of the patent
arrangement, namely to increase innovation and knowledge diffusion by granting exclusive rights.
Countries can improve the quality of disclosures by more rigorously enforcing the disclosure laws
that already exist. They can improve dissemination by encouraging and funding efforts by patent
offices to digitise the application process and put databases of patent information online. In
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
11 | SYNTHESIS
addition, a peer review system might be helpful because it is difficult for any individual patent
examiner to be skilled in every area. Another idea is to reduce the lag between the date of filing
and the date of publication (which is when public disclosure actually occurs). Shortening the lag,
at least in fast-moving technology fields, could make disclosures more useful by making it more
likely that the information they contain is still relevant.
•
A link between trade secrets and innovation is suggested by new OECD work. This report
presents an indicator of the stringency of protection of trade secrets, which provides a way to
study the relationship between the strength of trade secret protection in an economy and that
economy’s performance. The indicator is used to test the hypothesis that more stringent trade
secrets protection is associated with greater innovation and diffusion. The results show that there
is indeed a positive and statistically significant relationship between the stringency of trade secret
protection and indicators of innovation inputs. While these results do not mean that ever stronger
rights and remedies will yield similar results, the positive and statistically significant relationships
identified do indicate that adequately protecting trade secrets may be an appropriate policy for
strengthening certain aspects of economic performance.
•
Evidence on the importance of design rights is scarce and mixed. The number of industrial
designs contained in applications has been growing. However, one of the few studies that have
been performed on design IP found that while design is a significant part of the business model
for 85% of UK businesses, a mere four percent of them use registered designs; another four
percent use unregistered designs. Nevertheless, earlier work indicated that companies that were
“effective users of design” (but not necessarily design rights) outperformed the UK stock market
by 200 percent between 1994 and 2004. That raises questions about the effectiveness of design
rights for motivating investment in design-related KBC.
Introduction: The Context and Motivation for Knowledge-based Capital Phase 2
Knowledge-based Capital Phase 1
New Sources of Growth: Knowledge-based Capital is a strategic priority of the OECD, as recognised
by the 2012, 2013 and 2104 Meetings of OECD Council at Ministerial-level 3 and the Secretary General’s
Strategic Orientations. 4 It has benefited from the involvement of multiple committees and OECD
Directorates, thereby enabling a multi-disciplinary analysis.
New Sources of Growth: Knowledge-based Capital was born out of insights from the OECD’s
Innovation Strategy (2010). New Sources of Growth began in 2011. Phase 1 provided evidence of the
economic value of knowledge-based capital (see Box 1.1) as a new source of growth and identified current
and emerging policy challenges. It drew on expertise from across the OECD and from streams of work on
competition, corporate reporting, the efficiency of resource allocation, global value chains, innovation,
knowledge networks and markets, measurement and taxation. Phase 1’s main findings are summarised in
Annex 1.1 to this Chapter.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
12 | SYNTHESIS
Box 1.1
Knowledge-based capital and IP rights
Knowledge-based capital comprises a range of assets. These assets create benefits for firms but, unlike
machines, equipment, vehicles and structures, they have neither a physical nor a financial embodiment. This intangible
form of capital is, increasingly, the largest form of business investment and a key contributor to growth in advanced
economies. The term KBC, as defined and used in this report, can be used interchangeably with the term “intangible
assets.”
Some but not all KBC is protected by IP rights, which are exclusive rights held by the owners of assets that
qualify for legal protection under applicable IP laws. A significant portion of KBC is effectively ‘open’ in the sense that it
is not protected by IP rights.
The value of KBC depends on how effectively it is used. The use of KBC that is protected by IP rights depends, in
turn, on how effectively it is protected (so as to provide an incentive for creation and exploitation) as well as on ease of
access and the level of transaction costs
The Purpose and Structure of Knowledge-based Capital Phase 2
Taking into account the outcomes of phase 1, phase 2 of the project focuses on three specific types of
knowledge-based capital that need further explanation, hold the promise to generate growth and may
warrant improved policy making: i) intellectual property; ii) data and data analytics; and iii) economic
competencies (e.g. organisational capital, skills (human capital)).
Phase 2 therefore encompasses three streams of work: i) Enquiries into Intellectual Property’s
Economic Impact; ii) Data-Driven Innovation – Unleashing Data for Growth and Well-Being; and iii)
Economic Competencies. A stand-alone tax report, Taxation of Knowledge-based Capital: Non-R&D
Investments, Average Effective Tax Rates, Internal vs. External KBC Development and Tax Limitations,
has elements that relate to all three work streams.
Phase 2, conducted under the auspices of the Committee for Digital Economy Policy, involves seven
other OECD Committees: the Committee on Fiscal Affairs, the Committee on Industry, Innovation and
Entrepreneurship, the Committee on Consumer Policy, the Committee for Scientific and Technological
Policy, the Health Committee, the Public Governance Committee, and the Trade Committee.
The context of phase 2’s IP component: A changing landscape
One of phase 1’s main findings was that business investment in knowledge-based capital is linked to
growth and higher productivity. That link exists for two main reasons. First, in contrast to physical capital,
once the initial cost of developing some types of knowledge is borne, the cost is not re-incurred when the
knowledge is used again (in other words, KBC is “non-rivalrous”). That feature can create substantial
economies of scale in production. Second, investments in many types of KBC create knowledge spillovers,
which allow the benefits from an original investment to reverberate throughout multiple sectors of an
economy. Studies have shown that business investment in KBC contributes 20 to 27 percent of average
labour productivity growth in the European Union and the United States (OECD, 2013a at 6, 18, 20-22).
As a share of GDP, the business sector in higher-income economies invests proportionally more in KBC.
Figure 1.1, which is from the phase 1 report, illustrates that positive correlation (though it does not
establish causality).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
13 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.1.
Business Investment in KBC and GDP per capita, average 2000-2010
Source: (OECD, 2013a at 16).
The two features underlying KBC’s link to higher growth (non-rivalry and spillovers) contribute
directly to another key finding of phase 1, which was that KBC has become more prevalent in OECD
economies, not only spreading across many different industries but growing over time in the aggregate and
developing into the largest form of business investment in an increasing number of countries (OECD,
2013a at 12, 13). Considering that KBC encompasses intangible assets like software, databases, R&D,
worker training, market research, advertisement, and intellectual property, it is easy to see the point that
KBC investment today is widespread. Furthermore, KBC is becoming a more tradable asset that is taking
over the core of the global economy. Consider, for example, that most of the value in technology products
and medicines is not in the physical materials with which those goods are made, but in the continuum of
activities around the research, testing, and innovation required to develop them. Similarly, films, songs,
and books are bought and sold not because of the form they take but because of the creativity they reflect.
Even manufacturing staples like apparel can include substantial KBC, e.g. designs, in their value (Verdier,
2013.) As globalisation continues, the KBC inherent in those products is reaching, as well as emanating
from, more and more markets. In countries such as the United Kingdom, Australia, Japan, the United
States, and Canada, the significance of investment in KBC relative to investment in tangible capital has
been growing for years (OECD, 2013a at 13).
Because so much KBC is protected by intellectual property rights, and given the findings that KBC is
linked to growth and that it is becoming a more prevalent part of OECD economies, it is no surprise that
IP-protected capital has taken on an increasingly prominent and extensive role in economic activity, as
well. Whereas in some countries IP formerly had a smaller role and was considered relevant to a small
number of sectors such as pharmaceuticals, information technology, music and books, IP’s presence and
influence are now economy-wide (OECD, 2013a at pp. 9, 47-48). Accordingly, IP is now a mainstream
factor that has a substantial influence on economic performance in virtually every sector.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
14 | SYNTHESIS
While IP’s prominence has been growing, a number of developments have been significantly
changing the way IP is created, disseminated, appropriated and used. Some of those developments, such as
advances in digital technologies, have helped to make information more abundant, easier to access, and
easier to store and copy. Those developments have also made it easier to obtain and distribute IP illegally.
That accentuates the fact that IP rights are now more important than ever, as it is in everyone’s long-term
interest for stakeholders who create knowledge and artistic works to have well-defined, enforceable rights
to exclude third parties from appropriating their ideas or the expression of their ideas without permission.
This Report takes a closer look at IP’s role in OECD economies while examining some of the most
significant changes to the landscape in which it is operating. The Report targets several discrete areas
rather than attempting to cover every possible issue.
This section begins with brief descriptions of the various types of IP rights and the incentives they
provide. There is also a table that makes it easier to compare some of their important characteristics. These
are followed by a description of the key developments that are affecting how IP systems are operating
today.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
15 | SYNTHESIS
Box 1.2
Intellectual Property Rights and the Incentives They Provide
IP rights are exclusive rights held by the owners of a variety of knowledge-based assets that qualify for legal
protection under applicable IP laws. IP rights foster innovation, creativity, entrepreneurship, investment in knowledgebased assets, and growth. Types of IP and the incentives they bring about include:
•
•
•
•
•
Patents and utility models, which mainly protect new technology-based inventions, i.e. products or processes
that provide new ways of doing something or that offer new technical solutions to problems. Patents stimulate
innovation by assuring inventors that qualifying inventions will not be used or sold legally without their permission,
thereby enabling them (potentially) to recoup their investments and profit from them. Patents can also facilitate
financing for start-ups by signalling that a firm has valuable assets. To obtain a patent, one must disclose the
technical knowledge behind the invention, and patents eventually expire (generally 20 years after the filing date).
Patents can enable further technological developments through the information they disclose. They also provide
the security that can be necessary for licensing inventions.
Copyrights, which protect and reward literary, artistic and scientific works, whatever may be the mode or form of
5
their expression, including those in the form of computer programs and, in some jurisdictions, databases. Note,
however, that copyrights provide protection only against identical copies and non-original works, whereas
industrial property rights (patents, design rights, and trademarks) provide wider protection that works against
similar inventions or creations, too. Copyright laws also provide for certain exceptions and limitations. Their
protections typically last 50-70 years after the death of the creator (and shorter periods for works whose term of
protection is based on the date of fixation or communication to the public). Copyrights stimulate creativity by
assuring individuals and businesses, large and small, that the original, expressive material they create will not be
reproduced, adapted, communicated to the public, displayed, distributed or performed without their permission or
otherwise used in a manner that violates the exclusive rights of the copyright owners. Copyright laws provide a
foundation for and protect the opportunity of authors to obtain compensation, profit from, and take credit for the
material that they create.
Design rights, which protect new and/or original ornamental or aesthetic aspects of articles rather than their
technical features. Designs render objects more appealing to consumers and increase their marketability or
commercial value. By providing a measure of protection against unlicensed imitations, design rights promote
investments in proprietary designs that create value for both consumers and businesses. Registered designs are
generally valid for up to 15 years, but in some jurisdictions they are renewable up to a maximum of 25 years.
Trade secrets, which encompass confidential business and technical information and know-how that a firm
6
makes reasonable efforts to keep secret and that has economic value as a result. Trade secrets do not have a
fixed duration and can potentially last indefinitely. By offering a measure of protection for valuable information and
relieving businesses of the need to invest in more costly security measures, some trade secret laws may
encourage businesses to invest in the development of such information. Other trade secret laws focus solely on
the prevention of misappropriation of trade secrets. Trade secret laws may also encourage businesses to engage
in wider, though limited, dissemination of information than they otherwise would, such as by sharing sensitive
information (subject to confidentiality agreements) with business partners. In that manner, trade secret laws can
increase the likelihood of knowledge spill-overs.
Trademarks, i.e. distinctive words, symbols and brand names that help customers identify and purchase
products or services that meet their needs and expectations, e.g. in terms of quality or price. By protecting such
words and symbols, trademark laws encourage businesses to invest not only in developing brand names, but in
building strong reputations associated with those brands. Trademarks can be renewed indefinitely.
Geographical indications, which are signs used on goods having specific geographical origins and possessing
qualities or reputations that are essentially attributable to the place of origin. Geographical indications differ from other
types of IP rights in that they are a collective right rather than a unique right held by a particular individual or business.
Geographical indication protection can be renewed indefinitely
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
16 | SYNTHESIS
Table 1.1. Characteristics of Different Forms of IP
IPR
Patent
Trade Secret
Copyright
Design Right
Trademark
Duration
Usually 20 years
Indefinite
Usually 50-70
years after
creator’s death
Not more than 25
years in most
jurisdictions
Indefinite
Owner must
disclose
information
√
√ (if registered)
√
Protects against
independent
discovery
√
Protects against
unauthorised
production based
on reverse
engineering
√
Trait
√
√
Protects work in
progress
Must be new or
original
√
Must be useful
√
Must be
nonobvious
√
√
Must have value
√
√
Legal
enforcement cost
Expensive
√
√
√
√ (if registered)
√ (if registered)
√ (if registered)
Expensive
Less expensive
Less expensive
√
Must be secret
Registration fee
√
Expensive
The developments that have affected – and continue to affect – the generation, accumulation and
exploitation of IP include:
Internet and Information and Communication Technologies (ICT). The growth of the Internet,
including the mobile Internet, and advances in ICT capabilities have enhanced the interconnectedness of
economic agents worldwide, facilitated information flows within and across countries, and fostered the
development of the digital economy. 7 The Internet has enabled and encouraged innovation, new services
and applications, and brought them to a global user base. As a result, the Internet has fundamentally altered
the way people, businesses and governments interact. It is now an essential part of life in developed
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
17 | SYNTHESIS
countries, as well as in many developing countries. At the same time, however, the Internet has provided
opportunities for some to engage in unlawful conduct, including IP infringement.
The Internet’s growth is depicted in Figure 1.2, which shows that almost 40 percent of the world’s
population today is connected to the Internet, whereas 15 years ago less than five percent was connected.
Internet traffic has expanded even faster, reflecting higher volumes of data flow per user.
Figure 1.2.
Worldwide Internet Users and Traffic, 1995 to 2013
Note: The Internet penetration rate is the number of people using the Internet as a share of the world population.
* Estimate.
Source: OECD (2014a), p.5 (citing International Telecommunication Union (ITU), Cisco VNI).
Meanwhile, advances in storage technology have enabled consumers to store more and more content,
including on their mobile devices, enabling shifts in how, when, and where people consume, create, and
share content that is, for the most part, protected by copyright.
The digitisation of content protected by copyright. Advances in ICT have also led to a world in which
most commercial content, such as music, print media, and motion pictures, is digitised. The combination of
digitisation and Internet growth has made production and distribution faster and cheaper, enabled new,
innovative and successful businesses, and empowered the public to become creators and disseminators of
countless new creative works and sources of information and entertainment. Great strides have already
been made toward fulfilling the promise of digital technologies for creating, delivering, and consuming
content legally. However, it has also made illegal copying and misappropriation of some creative works
easier, instantaneous, free of charge, often profitable, and frequently without legal repercussions. The ease
of misappropriation has led copyright owners to take new measures designed to strengthen and better
protect their rights. They contend that, as a result of those measures, legitimate services are delivering a
wide variety of works in a wide variety of formats to consumers. Other stakeholders argue that the
measures have gone too far and are undermining legitimate exceptions for personal use and (in some
jurisdictions) fair use, and are interfering with innovation. Meanwhile, the growth of digital content has
also been accompanied by some confusion and frustration regarding the rules and terms of service in the
online marketplace among consumers who may expect the same rights over digital copies that they have
over physical copies (OECD, 2013d; Forbrukerrådet, 2007). Consumers would benefit from greater clarity
about their rights and obligations under copyright laws and licensing terms found under terms of service
and about how they can use digital products legally, safely and responsibly.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
18 | SYNTHESIS
Stronger IP rights. While it is not universally a recent trend, IP rights have generally been growing
stronger over the last 25 years. More types of inventions and creations have become eligible for protection
(e.g. synthetically produced genetic material and computer software can be patented in certain countries,
copyright protection has been extended to temporary copies in some jurisdictions, trademark scope has
expanded to include “non-traditional” marks such as smells, colours, aural marks, and motion marks), the
duration of copyright protection has generally been lengthened, some core and neighbouring rights have
been added (e.g. with respect to copyright, a right of communication to the public/making available, digital
performance rights, protection for technological protection measures, obligations concerning rights
management information), as have measures designed to improve enforcement and legal remedies (e.g.
border measures and ex officio powers for customs officers, pre-established/statutory damages, the
creation of an Office of the United States Intellectual Property Enforcement Coordinator in the White
House in 2013). 8 Some of these developments have resulted from obligations found in international
agreements, such as TRIPS, the WIPO Copyright Treaty and the WIPO Performances and Phonogram
Treaty.
The trend with respect to patent rights, for example, is expressed in Figure 1.3, using the OECD
average of a well-known patent rights index.
Figure 1.3.
Patent Rights Index, OECD Average Score*, 1985-2010
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Source: Chart generated with data from Park (2008) (and subsequent updates).
*The OECD average was compiled with a data set including 32 of the 34 countries that are OECD Members as of 2014 (data for
Estonia and Slovenia are not available; 1985 data for the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland, as well as 1990 data for the Czech
Republic, are also unavailable and therefore are not included in the average).
The numbers on the Y axis estimate the strength of a country’s patent protection regime on a scale of
1 to 5.The chart shows that the average strength of patent rights protection in OECD countries grew
considerably through 2005 and then levelled off during the next five years.
To some extent, the enhancement of IP rights is a reaction to the other two broad changes that have
been mentioned, Internet growth and digitisation. In other words, IP rights affect technology, and
technology also affects IP rights. A recent report by The United States Department of Commerce (2013, p.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
19 | SYNTHESIS
10), for example, identifies a list of “adjustments to copyright rights in the digital space” that have been
implemented to enable IP owners to “exploit their rights effectively”:
In the United States, the most notable adjustments to copyright rights in the digital space have
been the creation of a digital performance right for sound recordings; the application of the
reproduction right to temporary digital copies; and the establishment of legal regimes regarding
technological adjuncts to copyright, namely technological protection measures (TPMs) and
rights management information (RMI). At the international level, there has also been explicit
recognition of a “making available” right — i.e., the right to control making works available on
demand to members of the public. Each of these adjustments represented an attempt to ensure
that copyright owners retain the ability to exploit their rights effectively in the digital
environment.
The point of mentioning these changes to IP frameworks is that broader and stronger IP rights may
encourage more IP to be generated, or greater creativity to develop 9, and that leads to certain questions that
could interest policy makers: How much of that IP is translating into more innovation, jobs, creativity, and
productivity? Are IP rights currently calibrated to maximise innovation and growth? If not, how can they
be amended to achieve that goal? Alternatively, IP rights may still be too weak to keep pace with the
disruptive changes that have affected some industries, e.g. those in the creative economy. The questions for
policy makers remain the same in that case, though. Are IP rights currently maximising innovation and
growth? If not, how can they be adjusted to achieve that goal? This Report does not attempt to answer such
questions, but it does provide some tools and information that can help to develop answers.
The arrival of “big data”. Another effect of advances in ICT is that huge volumes of data and text
from many sources can be more efficiently collected, sifted, analysed and reassembled into new forms to
obtain a wide array of information and knowledge, and to identify correlations among different
components of the text and data sets. ICT and big data have changed the way in which knowledge is
created and, most importantly, appropriated and transferred. IP policies should balance the need to
encourage further development of data analytics technologies, the need to preserve incentives for content
creators and inventors, and the need for appropriate exceptions, such as for researchers under some
circumstances. 10,11
Globalisation. With trade liberalisation, greater trade flows, and more interdependence among
economies, many business processes have been fragmented along global value chains (GVCs). Figures 1.4
and 1.5 illustrate how much GVC’s evolved between 1995 and 2009. The size of the circles represents the
total amount of foreign value added embodied in an economy’s or a region’s total exports of goods and
services for final demand (household and capital consumption). The arrows show the origin of the
imported content and their thickness corresponds to the volume of the size of the flow they represent. Note
that the arrows thicken substantially between 1995 and 2009, indicating countries’ greater dependence on
imports.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
20 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.4.
Foreign Value Added Content of Exports, 1995
Selected flows, by source country/region, USD millions, at current prices
Source: OECD, 2013c, p. 40.
Figure 1.5.
Foreign Value Added Content of Exports, 2009
Selected flows, by source country/region, USD millions, at current prices
Source: OECD, 2013c, p. 41. See also ibid at pp. 250-251.
A consequence of globalisation is that different “parts” of a product may be subject to different IP
regimes in different countries. This development calls for IP systems that are able to accommodate the
more geographically diverse processes that businesses use to develop, manufacture, and distribute their
products. In addition, globalisation has encouraged more companies that sell globally to file for IP
protection in multiple jurisdictions. This is true not only for companies based in OECD countries, but for
companies that are based in developing countries. As these companies strive to protect their KBC in the
jurisdictions where they sell, they rely more and more on the capacity of IP systems in OECD countries.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
21 | SYNTHESIS
Furthermore, at least with respect to copyright, the larger the number of separate territories in which a
creative work is protected, the higher the transactions costs are for procuring global licenses (though
collective rights management can mitigate this problem). Consumer frustration may arise when terms and
conditions under which they access certain content do not permit the transmission of such content outside
the licensed territory. Finally, globalisation and interconnectedness have raised the profitability of
businesses that intentionally locate themselves in countries with weak IP protections so that they can
execute business models that would be considered to be based on IP infringement in OECD countries.
Convergence in science and technology, as well as the rise of open access, are leading to greater
intermingling of IP and more joint inventions. New technologies have been emerging out of the crossfertilisation of different technological and scientific fields. As the work of biologists, engineers, physicists
and people in many other fields becomes more integrated, scientists and entrepreneurs are finding
themselves immersed in multiple IP disciplines. Synthetic biology is a good example. It involves silica
modelling of DNA structures that are then created using real biological “parts” following a computer-aided
design approach. Consequently, elements of biology (typically protected by patents) and computer
programming (typically protected by copyright) are intermingled. In addition, phenomena such as open
access 12 and open innovation have increased the frequency of joint inventions and authorships. It may not
always be obvious how best to use IP frameworks to protect new hybrid technologies.
Greater complexity at a fast rate. Today, products often rely on multiple inventions. An example is
smart phones, which feature thousands of components, many of which are individually protected by IP
rights, especially patents and registered designs. This fragmentation of IP rights may exacerbate problems
like information asymmetries and hold-up, harming innovation and consumer welfare. Moreover, while
products are growing more complex, technology is also changing quickly and that has implications for IP.
Some industries have recently experienced a sharp acceleration in the pace at which innovation takes place
and have adopted partitioning strategies to protect their inventions. 13 These lead to shorter product life
cycles and possibly to patent congestion. 14
In contrast, some firms use the pace of technological change as an alternative to heavy reliance on
patent and registered design protection, staying ahead of competitors by innovating faster and making
previous inventions obsolete quickly. Note that those firms are likely relying on trade secrets protection to
some degree. The significance of that approach is reflected in some European innovation surveys that show
patents and registered designs are not necessarily viewed as the most effective way to protect innovation.
Instead, they reveal that most firms systematically consider lead time and secrecy to be more effective in
protecting innovation (e.g. Arundel, 2001; Hall, et al., 2012).
Moreover, some innovators avoid heavy reliance on IP because they are concerned that it could slow
innovation down. In their view, most innovation is incremental and if IP rights are too strong or too widely
used, IP will retard progress by planting landmines and erecting tollbooths for subsequent inventors. This
perspective originated with certain software hackers and academics and eventually helped to shape the
development of open-software platforms like Linux, Android and Chrome OS.
Furthermore, the pace of innovation in some industries is raising doubts in the minds of some
stakeholders about the universal suitability of IP systems for helping to solve major global challenges such
as climate change. This was illustrated by the decision of Tesla Motors to open its patent portfolio, which
Tesla said was a result of its disappointment with the slow pace of adoption of electric motor technology. 15
Knowledge Networks and Markets. Knowledge networks and markets (KNMs) comprise the wide
array of mechanisms and institutions facilitating the creation, exchange, dissemination and utilisation of
knowledge in its multiple forms. The common defining feature of these mechanisms is that they provide
critical services to actors in the innovation system throughout the process of exchanging knowledge and
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
22 | SYNTHESIS
associated rights. These services range from searching and matching to relevant counterparties and
knowledge objects, to evaluating, executing and enforcing agreements. Unprecedented levels of investment
in KBC and information have driven the emergence of new KNMs for financing innovation and licensing
IP, making it easier for start-up firms to secure the funding they need to develop their ideas (OECD,
2013b). For example, investment in KBC is encouraging new platforms (such as digital copyright
exchanges 16) that can make it easier, faster, and less expensive for firms, organisations and individuals to
exchange knowledge and associated IP rights.
IP policy challenges (identified in phase 1 and elsewhere) that are addressed in phase 2/IP
The number and speed of the changes affecting innovative products and processes pose challenges to
IP regimes. The phase 1 report identified many of those challenges. Other mainstream economic and policy
dialogues have revealed several more. A subset of those challenges motivated the specific work undertaken
in phase 2/IP. 17 That subset includes:
Estimating the economic significance of IP rights. Phase 1 showed that knowledge-based capital in
general is an increasingly important component of today’s OECD economies. But how much of that KBC
takes the form of IP, and what can we do to improve our understanding of the relationship of IP systems
for patent, copyright, design rights, and trade secrets to the performance of OECD economies? These
questions are addressed in Chapter 2, Measuring the Technological and Economic Value of Patents,
Chapter 4, An Empirical Assessment of the Economic Implications of Protection for Trade Secrets,
Chapter 5, Copyright in the Digital Era: Country Studies, and Chapter 6, Design and Design Frameworks.
Developing tools to identify the prospective economic and technological value of inventions protected
by patents. The challenge being addressed here is not so much a matter of estimating patents’ financial
value (although that problem requires attention, too), but rather their contributions to innovation. How can
we determine whether that type of value has, on average, increased, decreased, or stayed the same over
time? What methods are available to identify which sectors and countries tend to produce the most
technologically valuable patents? These questions are addressed in Chapter 2, Measuring the
Technological and Economic Value of Patents.
Identifying possible changes in society’s net gain from IP systems and what, if anything, to do about
them. IP rights effectively operate as an exchange between society and inventors/creators, rewarding
innovative and creative work while giving society the benefits of greater technological and creative
diffusion. 18 For example, governments award exclusive rights in the form of patents in exchange for the
disclosure of the technology in the patent filing and the ability to use the invention freely after 20 years in
most cases. Regarding copyrights, laws provide a framework that enables the author or copyright owner to
prohibit unauthorised copying and dissemination, thereby encouraging the author or owner to create and to
publish her creative work, and after a finite period the copyright expires and enters the public domain.
Furthermore, the IP exchange may be affected by broad changes that have been taking place in OECD
economies, such as the growth of the Internet, the proliferation of mobile devices, globalisation, the
digitisation of content, and the growing importance of IP both to society and to rights holders. How does
society benefit from existing IP regimes? How well does another form of KBC protection – trade secrets –
perform in terms of spurring knowledge diffusion and growth? Do any policy adjustments need to be made
to maximise IP’s contribution as an ongoing source of growth in OECD countries? These questions were
addressed by a group of 17 stakeholders who participated in a two-day Expert Workshop held in May 2014
as part of the phase 2/IP project. The discussions that took place at the Workshop are summarised in
Chapter 8. 19
Studying the mixed effects that IP systems may have on entry and innovation with respect to text and
data mining. Although they may encourage innovation, creativity, and diffusion, IP systems today may
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
23 | SYNTHESIS
occasionally obstruct those dynamics, as well. In an era of routine copying of digital text, data and images,
some stakeholders are concerned that copyright law can hinder the emergence of certain types of Internetbased firms, e.g. businesses based on data or text mining. Likewise, some are concerned that copyrights
and to some extent patents may impede scientists and other researchers who wish to use text and data
mining techniques. Other stakeholders assert that any such problems are being addressed through
innovative licensing strategies and market-based solutions or are already resolved through limitations such
as enumerated exceptions or the fair use doctrine. These issues are addressed in Chapter 5, Copyright in the
Digital Era: Country Studies, Chapter 7, Legal Aspects of Open Access to Publicly Funded Research, and
Chapter 8, Summary of the Expert Workshop.
Determining how copyright regimes can continue to reward creativity and innovation as well as
promote access by consumers and new businesses. Most commercial content is now legally available in a
digital format. That development, paired with the worldwide growth of Internet usage, has made copying,
distributing, and redistributing easier while making it harder to deter and prevent infringement. As a result,
commercial content is often accessed and appropriated illegally. Ideally, copyright policies and Internet
policies will work harmoniously and complementarily to promote creativity as well as innovation in the
digital economy. Ensuring that they do is, in the words of United States Secretary of Commerce Penny
Pritzker, “a critical and challenging task” (United States Department of Commerce Internet Policy Task
Force, 2013, p. ii).
Indeed, a variety of stakeholders have expressed concern that copyright laws have not kept pace with
evolving technology, and consequently several governments have conducted reviews of their copyright
laws. In the United States, the Register of Copyrights testified before a Congressional subcommittee last
year that although the United States’ copyright law is widely regarded as the most balanced in the world, it
“is showing the strain of its age and requires [Congress’] attention”. 20 The Chairman of the House
Judiciary Committee supports the idea of re-examining the law: “[I]t is my belief that a wide review of our
nation’s copyright laws and related enforcement mechanisms is overdue. . . [T]here is wide agreement that
the digital age has challenged our copyright laws in ways never imagined.” 21 Similarly, the EU’s
Commissioner for Digital Economy and Society has noted that while there continues to be a need to protect
intellectual property, copyright legislation also needs to be adapted to the digital era (Oettinger, 2015). 22
Some academics have weighed in, as well, agreeing that copyright laws need to be reformed. For
example, Gracz and di Filippi (2014) contend that copyright law has not adapted to the new reality of the
Internet and digital technologies, resulting in the loss of its ability to regulate social dynamics concerning
production, dissemination and access to creative works. “While copyright law has been, for many years, an
effective body of law, constantly evolving to adapt to on-going technological advances and social or
organisational changes, today, the copyright regime seems to have entered into a crisis, as the original
rationale of the law has progressively been disrupted by the advent of Internet and digital technologies, and
the radical change in contingencies that came along them” (ibid at 31).
Furthermore, a recent policy brief from the Lisbon Council states that “[c]opyright law is struggling to
adapt to the dynamic of digital technologies” (Hargreaves & Hugenholtz, 2013, at 1). It elaborates that
some researchers claim that copyright interferes with their work by obstructing text and data mining,
cultural organisations are not sure how to make their archives legally available for digital public use,
consumers have difficulty accessing content that should be available to them, creative industries cite the
financial effects of Internet-based infringements, authors say they are not being paid, some firms contend it
is too difficult to get cross-border licenses in Europe, and judges need more guidance on how to apply
copyright laws in the digital, online world.
Others agree that changes are necessary but focus more on the need for better enforcement. For
example, in a piece supporting proposed legislation to combat online piracy, Castro (2010) argues that
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
24 | SYNTHESIS
more robust copyright enforcement in the digital realm would not only be desirable for content creators,
but it would make consumers better off. A recent report by the United States Department of Commerce
Internet Policy Task Force (2013, p. 41) takes a balanced approach, noting that “there are a number of
respects in which the existing array of tools against infringement has become insufficient” and that “[t]he
tools for protecting and enforcing rights must keep pace – as with rights and exceptions, they need regular
updating.”
Still other commenters believe the current laws are sufficiently flexible to enable adaptation to the
digital age, at least within the EU. See, for example, Depreeuw & Hubin (2014) and Charles River
Associates (2014). Indeed, there are academics and stakeholders who believe that copyright is not an
obstacle either to the development of business on the Internet or to access to science and culture. Instead,
they contend that most of the identified roadblocks are linked to other issues such as cultural traditions and
linguistic differences, as well as certain commercial practices by IT companies themselves, differences
regarding the level of taxation, or cross-border payment difficulties.
Thus digital technologies have presented new opportunities for creative industries and consumers but
have also brought a host of complex legal and other challenges for creators, consumers, and policy makers.
The resulting discussion too often has been characterised as a clash of two extreme positions. That is an
oversimplification because the choices are not binary and, in reality, there are multiple positions. One of
them is that digitisation and the growth of the Internet diminished copyright protection and effective
enforcement, thereby harming incentives to fund, create, and distribute new artistic material. Another view
is that copyright is impeding innovation, creativity, free expression, and emerging businesses, and limiting
consumer access to and use of creative works, so there should be more exceptions. But there are multiple
gradations of thought between those two poles. Moreover, value may be found in innovation outside of
policy making or through voluntary activities in the private sector. Accordingly, there are also stakeholders
who argue that new licensing strategies and access control technologies, for example, are overcoming the
problems associated with digitisation and the Internet while providing consumers with access to a wider
range of content than they have ever had. Recently, the debate appears to be shifting toward a thoughtful
assessment of the current balance of rights, exceptions, and responsibilities in the copyright system, taking
into account the interests of all stakeholders.
In particular, several governments have completed or initiated comprehensive reviews of their
copyright laws. That group includes the following, among others:
•
The United Kingdom’s Prime Minister commissioned the Hargreaves Report, which looked into
ways that the copyright regime might be reformed to work more effectively in the digital era
(Hargreaves, 2011). The government implemented several of those reforms in 2014, including
new exceptions for text and data mining for non-commercial research (Intellectual Property
Office & Viscount Younger of Leckie , 2014), and for personal copying for private use and
parody, character and pastiche, and an extended exception for quotation (Intellectual Property
Office, 2014).
•
In the United States, the Department of Commerce’s Internet Policy Task Force observed in a
July 2013 report that while “[d]igital distribution and a proliferation of consumer-friendly
devices have given American consumers more choices than ever in how they access and enjoy
copyrighted works . . . we face a renewed challenge to assure that copyright law continues to
strike the right balance between protecting creative works and maintaining the benefits of the
free flow of information.” 23 As noted, the House of Representatives’ Judiciary Committee is
conducting a wide review of United States copyright laws and enforcement mechanisms to
determine whether they need updating in the digital age.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
25 | SYNTHESIS
•
The European Commission (2012) is undertaking a process to modernise the copyright
framework to make it suitable for the digital age.
•
The Australia Law Reform Commission (2014) conducted an inquiry on copyright exceptions in
the digital economy.
•
The Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs commissioned a law and economics research report
exploring the possibility of introducing more flexibility into the system of exceptions and
limitations in Dutch copyright law (Van der Noll, et al., 2012).
•
Canada reformed its copyright law in 2012 to better account for the impact of the Internet and
digitisation. 24
•
In 2013, Ireland’s Copyright Review Commission released a report weighing the possibility of
modernising the copyright law (Copyright Review Commission (Ireland), 2013).
The public debate involves several difficult policy questions. The Internet has enabled the
development of a vastly improved digital marketplace of creative works and more of them are becoming
available to more people in new and diverse platforms. Still, more work remains to reach the full potential
of the digital marketplace. How can governments provide an appropriate level of protection – one that will
encourage creative expression and foster new, innovative firms whose legitimate business models depend
on copyrighted digital content? At the same time, what can governments do to facilitate consumers’ lawful
access to the broadest possible array of digital content? How have enhanced enforcement remedies actually
affected creative content generation, consumption, dissemination, and innovation in the digital era? Should
they be complemented by other measures (e.g. consumer education, more efficient markets for licensing
digital content)? Are current statutory exceptions to copyright protection still adequate? How do those
exceptions affect copyright owners, creative output, and social welfare? While those broad questions
cannot be definitively answered anywhere, including in this Report, information that is helpful in
addressing them appears in the Chapter 5, Copyright in the Digital Era: Country Studies, and Chapter 8,
Summary of the Expert Workshop.
Are IP systems meshing well with open access initiatives? Internet growth, content digitisation, and
expanding “big data” and data analytics capabilities have also affected the ways in which publicly funded
research results are accessed, disseminated and used. It has become increasingly easy to share and process
such information. Generally speaking, “open access” refers to greater access to scientific articles and data
produced from publicly funded research, which can lead to more collaboration, greater dissemination of
results, and increased engagement with society. 25
Open access raises a number of IP policy questions, though, such as how to delimit research
exceptions to copyright. Both the benefits and the risks of greater openness in science should be well
understood, but the optimal degree of openness with respect to public research is not obvious. For example,
competition drives excellence in science and innovation, but making all aspects of every researcher’s work
publicly available would be detrimental to incentives to compete and therefore to the quality of the results.
Researchers want to disseminate their papers widely and gain prestige, but they usually do not want to give
away their underlying data for others to use.
How does IP affect the efficiency of research systems and the speed of knowledge diffusion? Other
IP-related open access questions include how to define research exemptions, how to optimise licensing
schemes for all stakeholders, data use and re-use, and IP rights for large datasets that are automatically
generated by machines. These topics are discussed in Chapter 7, Legal Aspects of Open Science and Open
Data and Chapter 8, Summary of the Expert Workshop.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
26 | SYNTHESIS
Aims of Phase 2/IP
The main objectives for phase 2’s IP project, in responding to the policy challenges set out above,
may be summarised as:
•
To identify better measurement techniques, statistics and indicators to underpin the analysis of IP’s
relationship to economic performance, innovation, productivity and growth
•
To improve understanding of the role of IP in economic performance, innovation, productivity and
growth
•
To improve understanding of how digitisation, globalisation and the growth of the Internet are
affecting IP use, enforcement, system effectiveness 26, and policy
The following section sets out the report’s key findings in support of those objectives.
Key Findings
The Importance of IP to OECD Economies
Whether it is appraised in terms of its connection with investment in KBC, salaries, exports, or value
added, intellectual property’s economic impact is significant and has grown considerably over the past 25
years. Expanding not only in overall magnitude but across sectors, IP-protected capital has become an
increasingly important component of advanced economies. Among the various types of IP, copyright
stands out for the growth in and level of the investment it attracts, as well as its connection to job growth,
according to the available data.
Looking at evidence on IP’s aggregate role, three main points emerge: IP’s economic importance has
grown over time, investment in IP-protected assets was resilient during the recent recession, and that
investment is growing much faster than investment in physical assets.
Figure 1.6, for example, illustrates all three of those points. It shows that total nominal investment in
intangible assets protected by IP rights (represented by the blue line, which aggregates investments in
copyrights, trademarks, registered and unregistered designs, and patents) in the United Kingdom was more
than 2.5 times greater in 2011 than it was in 1990. It also shows that investment in IP rights barely declined
after the financial crisis of 2008 and has since recovered. In addition, it shows that nominal investment in
tangible assets was lower in 2011 than it was in 1998. Meanwhile, investment in IP-protected assets as a
share of all investment in intangible assets held steady throughout the 21-year period at just under 50
percent in most years. Finally, total investment in IP-protected assets as a share of investment in tangibles
grew from 36 per cent to 72 percent between 1990 and 2011 (see Table 2, as well). On the whole, the
figure reveals that between 1990 and 2011 the United Kingdom transformed from a mainly tangibles-based
economy to an economy driven primarily by intangibles, of which IP-protected assets are a major
component. Note that the IP line does not include investment in assets protected by trade secrets.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
27 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.6.
Total UK Investment in Tangible and Intangible Assets, including IP (nominal billions of GBP)
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
Source: The figure is derived from data in Goodridge, Haskel, & Wallis (2014), pp. 9, 29 and from supplementary data kindly provided
by Professor Goodridge.
WIPO data on worldwide IP filing trends, while different from data measuring monetary investment
in IP, nevertheless suggest that the United Kingdom’s experience is not unique, at least with respect to the
points that IP’s economic significance is growing and that it was resilient during the recession. Global
filings for patents and registered designs declined in 2009, but they have recovered sharply and are now
growing even faster than they were before the crisis. In 2012, patent filings grew by 9.2 percent, faster than
any other annual increase in the past 18 years. Industrial design counts grew by an all-time record rate of
17 percent (WIPO, 2013).
Another report (United States Department of Commerce, 2012) also uses a different type of data but
paints a picture of IP’s overall economic significance that is roughly consistent with the reports from
WIPO and the United Kingdom. Taking into account patents, trademarks, and copyright, this report
identifies a group of 75 United States industries as IP-intensive. It then finds that there were 27.1 million
jobs in those industries in 2010, which was 18.8 percent of all jobs in the United States economy. In terms
of value-added, the IP-intensive industries contributed just over USD 5 trillion, or nearly 35 percent of
GDP. Moreover, direct employment in the wake of the global financial crisis recovered 60 percent faster in
IP-intensive industries than it did in non-IP intensive industries (comparing 2011 to 2010). Jobs in the IPintensive sectors had higher average salaries, as well – 42 percent higher in 2010. What is more, IPintensive industries exported more than 60 percent of all the merchandise exported by United States
industries in 2010.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
28 | SYNTHESIS
Similar or higher figures exist for the contributions of IP-intensive industries to the European Union’s
GDP (38.6 percent) and to total employment in the EU (77 million jobs, or 35 percent of the total), with
average earnings in these industries around 40 percent higher than the overall average across the economy.
Furthermore, IP-intensive industries account for more than 90 percent of all the merchandise exported from
the EU (European Patent Office & OHIM, 2013). IP’s economic resilience is also reflected in detailed
service sector statistics on the IP “leasing” sector in the United States. Total revenues in the sector
amounted to USD 20 billion in 2010, a four percent (nominal) increase over 2009, which is notable
considering that the economy was in recession at that time (OECD 2013b, p. 11).
One more message that emerges from these numbers is that IP is no longer a boutique policy
consideration, relevant to only a small number of industries. It has become more prominent as investment
in intangible assets has gained ground on and, in some economies, overtaken investment in tangible assets.
IP now reaches into more sectors than ever before. “IP is used everywhere in the economy, and IP rights
support innovation and creativity in virtually every U.S. industry” (United States Department of
Commerce, 2012). IP has reached a point where it warrants mainstream consideration, akin to competition,
tax or trade policy.
Various types of data are also available on the relative economic significance of different types of IP
rights. Table 1.2, for example, shows patterns of UK market sector investment in copyright, design,
trademarks, and patents from 1990 to 2011.
Table 1.2.
UK Market Sector Investment in Tangibles, Intangibles, and IPRs (nominal £billions)
1990
1995
2000
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
Investment in Patents
2.9
3.3
4.3
5.1
5.2
5.8
5.9
5.8
5.9
6.3
Investment in Copyright
9.2
14.0
22.1
29.3
26.7
28.6
29.9
27.0
29.1
30.1
Investment
Design
Registered
1.0
1.0
1.4
1.7
1.7
1.9
1.9
1.8
1.8
1.9
Unregistered
5.9
6.1
8.3
10.1
10.6
11.3
11.5
11.1
11.1
11.2
Investment in Trademarks
4.8
6.7
10.2
11.7
12.7
13.2
13.4
13.1
13.5
14.0
Total Investment in IPRs
23.8
31.1
46.3
57.8
56.9
60.6
62.5
58.9
61.4
63.5
Total Investment in Intangibles
47.9
63.9
92.1
118.1
118.6
125.5
128.3
123.3
127.6
126.8
Total Investment in Tangibles
66.9
66.5
93.8
100.1
102.2
116.4
111.8
92.0
94.4
87.9
Investment
Design
in
in
Source: Goodridge, Haskel, & Wallis (2014), pp. 9, 29 and supplementary data kindly provided by Professor Goodridge. Note that
trade secrets are not included in this table.
The table reveals several notable facts about investment in particular types of IP in the economy of the
United Kingdom:
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
29 | SYNTHESIS
•
Investment in patents is quite small relative to investment in assets protected by copyright,
unregistered design, and trademarks. In 2011, investment in patents was just 21 percent of the
investment in copyright, for example.
•
Investment in copyright has grown more than investment in any other form of IP (with the
possible exception of trade secrets), more than tripling on a nominal basis between 1990 and
2011. Growth in investment protected by trademark was a close second, growing slightly less
than threefold during that period.
•
Copyright, as of 2011, was by far the largest component of IP-protected investment (again,
putting trade secrets aside as a possible exception), drawing more than twice the amounts
invested in unregistered design and trademarks, respectively. Of all investment in IP rights, 47
percent was in copyright, 22 percent in trademark, 18 percent in unregistered design rights, 10
percent in patents, and three percent in assets protected by registered design rights.
•
Investment in unregistered designs is substantial, approaching the level of investment in
trademarks.
Copyright also has a strong showing in employment data from the United States. Figure 1.7 shows
that job growth in copyright-intensive industries far outpaced that in trademark and patent-intensive
industries from 1990 to 2011. In fact, employment contracted in the latter industries during that period, and
markedly so with respect to the patent-intensive group.
Figure 1.7.
Indexed Employment in IP-Intensive US Industries, 1990-2011
Source: (United States Department of Commerce, 2012, p. 40). Note that the Figure does not account for design right- intensive or
trade secret-intensive industries.
Notably, copyright protects a significant amount of software investment in much of the world
(especially where software is mostly not patentable) and, in terms of employment and gross value added,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
30 | SYNTHESIS
the IT, software, and computer services sector sometimes overshadows the rest of the ‘creative industries’
(Department for Culture, Media & Sport, 2014).
To the extent that this chapter devotes more space to copyright issues than to issues related to other
types of IP, a key reason is that according to the available data, copyright’s dynamic role in economies
appears to be more prominent than that of other kinds of IP.
Copyrights
Whereas patents protect ideas, copyrights protect the expression of ideas. But both forms of IP
address the same underlying problem: if anyone is free to use or copy the inventions and creations of
others, then the incentive to produce those inventions and creations dwindles. Effective copyright
protection motivates creative outputs as well as their legitimate dissemination to the public.
Analysis of copyright’s role in economic performance is significantly hindered by a lack of data (see
section 3.7). Chapter 5 of this Report provides an indication of copyright’s performance, though, with a set
of 12 country studies. 27 Those studies illustrate how copyright-intensive industries 28 have performed, in
terms of the value added and employment they provided 29, as they adapted to Internet growth, content
digitisation, and globalisation. While the adaptation process is necessarily incomplete because technology
will continue to evolve, the country studies suggest on the whole that the economic performance of
copyright-intensive industries has been stable so far. When one considers that the period studied 30 includes
a substantial and sustained global economic downturn, the “stable” performance takes on a more
impressive aura.
Most of the countries in the sample reported positive growth, on average, in the value added generated
by copyright-intensive industries. That corresponds with a total change (across the whole time range
examined for each country, not per annum) in the share of GDP for the copyright-intensive sectors that
ranged from a decline of 1.5 percent to an increase of 0.9 percent.
Employment figures for the copyright-intensive industries paint an overall similar, stable picture.
During the analysed periods in the sample countries for which data are available, the number of employees
in copyright-intensive sectors either grew or underwent a slight contraction. In the most recent year for
which data are available (depending on the country), the copyright-intensive industries employed 2.3 to 5.6
percent of the workforce.
Patents
Global filings for patents are now growing faster than they were before the financial crisis struck. In
2012, they grew by more than 9 percent, the fastest annual increase in 18 years (WIPO, 2013, p. 6). The
number of patents granted worldwide also grew in 2012. The increase of 13.7 percent over 2011 propelled
the total above one million for the first time. Moreover, approximately 8.7 million patents were in force in
2012 (ibid at 7).
In addition, during the past few years, companies have paid previously unheard of amounts to acquire
other companies’ patent portfolios. In some cases, buyers simply buy an entire patent-rich firm. For
example, Google acquired Motorola and its extensive collection of patents for more than USD 12.5 billion
(though, in the end, Google kept only Motorola’s patent portfolio, selling off other parts of the business,
and it estimates that the portfolio cost between 2.5 to 3.5 billion (Helft, 2014)). Nortel auctioned off its
patent portfolio for USD 4.5 billion.
While trends in patent filings and grants, as well as their market value in some high profile
transactions, begin to provide a sense of patents’ economic significance, homing in on their relationship
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
31 | SYNTHESIS
with innovation is a more elusive goal. It introduces a great deal of complexity. The effects of patents on
innovation vary substantially from industry to industry, making it difficult to describe the relationship in
universal terms. But it can be said that when academics started to examine the role that patents play in
innovation in the 1980s, they found that patents were less crucial than many had believed. Firms in only a
small number of industries, such as the chemical and pharmaceutical industries, tended to mention patents
as an important factor in motivating their R&D investments. Elsewhere, patents were not considered to be
very effective in protecting innovations (Levin, et al., 1987).
A later study showed that most firms rely on patents the least among various methods for protecting
the returns from their inventions, whereas secrecy and lead time are used most heavily (Cohen, et al., 2000,
based on a survey of nearly 1500 R&D labs in the United States manufacturing sector). Indeed, while
results varied by sector, the authors concluded with respect to product innovations that “patents are
unambiguously the least central of the major appropriability mechanisms overall” and that “in no industry
are patents identified as the most effective appropriability mechanism” (Cohen, et al., 2000 at 9). 31 In
another survey (Jankowski, 2012), more businesses in the United States identified trademarks and trade
secrets as important forms of IP protection than any other. Copyrights were third, followed by patents.
Nevertheless, there has been a surge in the number of patents issued during the past 20 years or so.32
A possible explanation for that is simply that there has been a sizeable increase in innovative activity, so
there is more to patent. Several empirical studies have cast doubt on greater innovation as the primary
cause, though. Instead, the studies attribute the patent surge to factors such as declining patent application
fees and growing pressure to build up large patent portfolios for the purpose of negotiating with other
patent holders. 33 Furthermore, the picture is muddled by the fact that China has been the main engine
behind the surge in recent years (WIPO, 2013, pp. 3, 49), which could reflect either greater innovation
taking place there or that globalisation has strengthened Chinese inventors’ incentives to file for patent
protection – or both.
In principle, patents encourage innovation in several ways. First, they give inventors greater
incentives to invent by providing a measure of protection against imitators, who might otherwise let the
inventor do all the hard and costly work of developing a technology and then simply copy it, making it
difficult for the inventor to earn an attractive return. Second, in exchange for that protection, patents
require the inventor to tell the public that the technology exists, to explain how it works, and to forfeit
exclusive rights to the invention after a fixed period (usually 20 years). That enhances the process of
knowledge diffusion by helping others to understand the invention and improve upon it or incorporate it in
a new invention of their own. In other words, there is a technology spill-over effect that stimulates new
ideas. Another benefit of disclosure is that it tends to decrease redundant R&D investments by firms who
might otherwise continue trying to develop exactly the same technology. Finally, patents add to knowledge
diffusion by facilitating exchanges via licensing agreements.
A number of countries began to strengthen their patent rights in the 1980s and have generally
continued to do so. As a result, patentability extended into new fields, the rights themselves were
enhanced, and they generally became easier to obtain. Commentators began to raise concerns in the late
1990s that too many patents were being issued, that their claims were too broad, and that the rights they
conferred on patent holders were too strong. 34 The result, the critics claimed, was that innovation was
actually being discouraged because it had become so difficult and costly to identify the patents that might
be relevant to an invention and to pay for any necessary licenses.
Mark Lemley (2008) asserts that companies in some sectors have responded with an unexpected
approach: They ignore patents.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
32 | SYNTHESIS
[B]oth researchers and companies in component industries simply ignore patents. Virtually
everyone does it. They do it at all stages of endeavour. From the perspective of an outsider to the
patent system, this is a remarkable fact. And yet it may be what prevents the patent system from
crushing innovation in component industries like IT. Ignoring patents, then, may be a
‘workaround’ that allows the innovation system to function in the face of overbroad patent
protection. 35
Many empirical studies have been conducted to analyse the effects of changes in patent protection.
Some of them concluded that while stronger patent rights contribute to a significant increase in the number
of patents granted, they have little effect on R&D expenditures, which suggests that they are not boosting
innovation significantly. 36 Other studies suggested that expanding patent rights into new areas like
software led to a kind of patent stampede, in which firms rushed to collect patents on existing technologies
for use as bargaining chips in licensing negotiations (Bessen & Hunt, 2004). Still others found that policy
changes such as raising the amount of compensation awarded in patent infringement litigation are not
perceived by firms as having a significant impact on their innovative activity (Motohashi, 2004). Finally, a
recent OECD study using panel regression techniques to assess determinants of private sector innovative
activity, proxied by R&D expenditure, across 19 countries found that strengthening patent rights had no
statistically significant effect on firms’ R&D investment (Westmore, 2013, pp. 21).
To help shed more light on the patent-innovation relationship, Chapter 2 of this Report provides a way
to estimate the technological and economic value of patented inventions and the impact they may have on
subsequent technological developments by proposing 13 indicators. 37 The indicators use measurable
factors such as patent family size, backward citations, forward citations, and patent renewal. These factors
enable analysis at the individual patent level as well as at the aggregate patent portfolio level. They can be
used to study policy-relevant topics such as: firms’ innovation strategies and performance; enterprise
dynamics, including the drivers of enterprise creation and of mergers and acquisitions; the determinants of
productivity; the output of R&D activities and the returns to R&D investments; and the output of
universities and public research organisations. The Chapter therefore paves the way for future work that
could better illuminate the contribution of patents to innovation and productivity.
So far, the indicators developed in Chapter 2 have been “test-driven” with statistics compiled from
patent applications filed with the European Patent Office (EPO) during the period 1990-2009 and sorted
according to the country of residence of the applicants. 38 Each indicator suggests that some countries have
relatively strong innovative abilities and that some have relatively average or weak abilities. The results
vary from indicator to indicator. But Chapter 2 also includes an experimental composite index that is based
on a group of several relevant factors, whereas the other indicators look at only one factor at a time. OECD
researchers generated results using three different definitions for this composite index, and those results
were consistent in that they all suggest (again, this takes into account only EPO data):
•
The average technological and economic value of inventions protected by patents has eroded
over time, at least through 2004. 39 There might be a number of reasons for that erosion, including
procedural aspects like patent application backlogs as well as strategic behaviours like defensive
patent filings
•
Patented micro and nano technologies have the highest economic and technological value
(although there is a relatively small number of observations in that sector)
•
Australia, Canada, Norway, South Africa, and the United Kingdom are the countries with the
highest average technological and economic patent values.
The graphical results derived from one of the three versions of the composite index 40 appear in Figure
1.8 for illustrative purposes.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
33 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.8.
Composite Index of Patent Value, 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Patent Value Index, average by technology field
1994
Patent Value Index, average by economy
2004
1994
2004
EPO patents, 2004
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
0.0
45671
South Africa
2730
Australia
1587
1464
2188
Canada
Norway
455
1757
25
695
1043
1863
United Kingdom
Denmark
Ireland
Korea
Sweden
311
United States
616
2746
Finland
1991
Luxembourg
1167
1589
1297
France
408
Netherlands
Israel
961
Switzerland
768
663
25
1139
541
1980
1697
1885
1447
1470
596
2136
3336
0.1
0.2
0.3
Italy
Belgium
World average
Brazil
Singapore
Japan
Spain
China
India
Germany
926
789
Austria
1380
Chinese Taipei
0.4
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
Note: The composite index of patent value is based on the average value of its normalised component, by cohort of filing date and
technology fields. The average by economy is provided only for economies with more than 50 patents reporting the index in 2004.
The index is based on patent applications filed with the European Patent Office during the period 1990-2009. The economies listed
in the “Patent Value Index, average by economy” refer to the country of residence of the applicants. The index does not intend or
enable a comparison of the value of national patents of different economies.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012. The small numbers on the right hand of the
average by technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
It must be emphasised that these results are a function of the particular data set and time period used.
The purpose of showing them here is to provide an example of what the composite indicator can do. It is
certainly possible that the results will be substantially different when data from another patent office and/or
from another time period are used in the indicator algorithms.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
34 | SYNTHESIS
As mentioned above, the patent value indicators could be used to study a variety of research topics of
potential interest to policy makers. In fact, the OECD’s Economics Department has already used them as
part of an econometric study of the extent to which changes in the patent stock are associated with flows of
capital and labour to patenting firms (OECD, 2014b). Specifically, the study used the radicalness indicator
(roughly defined as measuring how different an invention is from existing inventions) in concluding that
when firms add patents that have higher-than-average radicalness scores, they experience larger-thanaverage increases in employment, capital stock, and turnover, among other factors. The study also found
that young firms are more likely to file radical patents than older firms (OECD, 2014b, p. 26 and Tables 7
and B7).
The indicators could also be used, for example, to learn more about patent assertion entities (PAEs)
and the environments in which they operate. That type of work has not been done, nor is it planned at the
OECD, but it is an example of the indicators’ many potential applications. PAEs are firms that generally do
not invest in research, apply for patents or use patents to produce goods and services, but rather acquire
patents and use them to generate licensing revenues through negotiation and litigation. PAEs were
traditionally viewed as benign or even beneficial entities that help small inventors to profit from their
inventions. More recently, the behaviour of some PAEs has raised concerns that they are exploiting low
quality patents (meaning patents with inaccurate claims or patents awarded for inventions that are not
genuinely novel or non-obvious), combined with the high cost of litigation in patent systems, to achieve
unjustified settlements. Such behaviour could increase the cost of the affected products and retard
innovation.
PAEs can be aggressively litigious, using infringement lawsuits, and the threat of filing them, to
persuade or force other firms to pay for licenses. The impact of PAEs in some jurisdictions, particularly the
United States where patent litigation is very expensive and courts do not traditionally require the loser to
pay the cost of litigation, raises questions about the economic nature of the patents that PAEs use to drive
their business model. Do they tend to have relatively high technological and economic value? Relatively
low values? Do they merit the incomes they are generating in settlements and infringement awards?
Litigation statistics suggest that these questions are worth investigating. A report by the United States
Government Accountability Office (2013) found that the number of defendants in patent infringement
lawsuits increased by nearly 130 per cent between 2007 and 2011, with PAEs responsible for about 20 per
cent of the lawsuits during that period. A newer study by PricewaterhouseCoopers (PwC) (2014) indicates
that the latter figure has already risen substantially since 2011. It shows that PAEs now account for 67
percent of all new patent lawsuits in the United States – and that has happened during a period when
growth in the total number of patent lawsuits filed is outpacing growth in patents granted (see Figure 1.9).
In other words, there is more patent litigation than ever, and a large and increasing share of it is due to
PAEs.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
35 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.9.
Growth in Patent Case Filings versus Patents Granted (US), 1991-2013
Years are based on September year-end.
Source: PricewaterhouseCoopers (July 2014), based on data from United States Patent and Trademark Office, Performance &
Accountability Report Fiscal Year 2013, and United States Courts, Judicial Facts and Figures 2012.
In addition, the PwC study shows that while the median monetary award in patent lawsuits is
generally declining, the median award to PAEs has been growing since 2005 and is now more than three
times higher than the median award to practising entities (see Figure 1.10).
Figure 1.10.
Median Damages Awarded in United States Patent Lawsuits, Practicing v. Non-Practising
Entities
Median damages adjusted for inflation to 2013 dollars. Number of identified decisions is indicated within the respective columns of the
left panel.
Source: PricewaterhouseCoopers, 2014 Patent Litigation Study (July 2014).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
36 | SYNTHESIS
These trends add up to a substantial impact. A new study by Bessen and Meurer (2014) finds that
more than 5,000 companies were named as defendants in lawsuits by PAEs in the United States in 2011
alone and that they incurred more than USD 29 billion in direct costs as a result. Most of the defendants
were SMEs, i.e. the type of firms that tend to contribute greatly to productivity and job growth but are least
able to cope with the cost of lawsuits (Hargreaves, 2011, p. 10).
Concerns about PAEs are spilling over into the European Union. In 2013, 16 large technology
companies from around the world sent an open letter to EU Member States warning that draft procedural
rules for a new Unified Patent Court could encourage PAEs to ramp up abusive litigation in Europe. 41
However, much remains unknown about PAEs, the net effect of their activities, and what the future holds
for them. Recent changes to the jurisprudence and patent laws of the United States have weakened the
position of PAEs in litigation, for example, by limiting the availability of injunctions against infringers,
providing new alternatives to challenge a patent’s validity, increasing the likelihood that a wrongfully
accused defendant can recover its fees, and requiring heightened economic evidence to support damages
requests. Implemented as a component of an econometric study, the patent value indicators might help to
shed some light on the nature of the patents that PAEs are using to collect their royalties.
Trade secrets
The term “trade secrets” essentially means confidential business and technical information and knowhow that a firm makes reasonable efforts to keep secret and that has economic value as a result. (See
Chapter 3, Approaches to the Protection of Trade Secrets.) Estimating the economic value of trade secrets
is challenging due to the secrecy requirements. However, some indications of their value and importance
do exist. Almeling et al. (2010), for example, estimate that the annual cost of trade secret theft to United
States firms is as high as USD 300 billion. Interviews with members of the European Chemical Industry
Council have revealed that misappropriation of a trade secret or confidential business information often
costs a firm up to 30 per cent of its revenue and sometimes much more (CEFIC, 2012). A panellist in the
workshop noted that there is considerable anecdotal evidence that trade secrets can be worth substantial
amounts, insofar as violation can lead to large damages actions or settlements (Chapter 8 of this Report).
For example, in a case in which an alleged spy from Huawei was criminally indicted for having stolen
trade secrets from Motorola, the latter claimed that the R&D costs of the stolen information exceeded USD
600 million (Anderlini, 2010).
Moreover, in a recent European Commission-sponsored survey of more than 500 businesses, 75 per
cent of the respondents ranked trade secrets as “strategically important to their company’s growth,
competitiveness and innovative performance” (European Commission, 2013). That ranking was consistent
across firms of all sizes, including SMEs. Furthermore, surveys by Cohen, et al. (2000) and (Jankowski,
2012) show that firms rate secrecy as being among the very most important means of protecting
innovation. In many countries, the relative ease of use and lack of registration requirements for trade
secrets have led SMEs to rely on trade secrets as the default mode of IP protection (Brant and Lohse,
2013). Another factor that may contribute to their popularity among SMEs is that, unlike copyright and
patent law, trade secrets law is not especially technical.
In theory, trade secret protection encourages investment in R&D and the development of
commercially valuable information in various interdependent ways. First, it can make the fruits of that
investment more appropriable (by deterring employees, business partners and third parties from
misappropriating or misusing information that qualifies as a trade secret). 42 Second, trade secrets can
provide competitive advantages and therefore motivate investment in them through the enticement of
supra-competitive profits (Lemley, 2011). For example, a trade secret might cover a cost-saving production
process or a unique product. Third, in some cases trade secrets motivate investment in R&D and valuable
knowledge by serving as an alternative or a complement to patent protection. This can occur, for instance,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
37 | SYNTHESIS
when KBC does not meet the requirements for obtaining a patent, a patent is considered too expensive to
procure and maintain, or seeking one is deemed undesirable due to the disclosure requirement (Maskus,
2000; Friedman, et al., 1991). Trade secrets can also provide protection during the developmental phase
prior to a formal patent application. In some cases, firms prefer to use trade secrets protection due to their
immediate availability and/or potentially lower costs (e.g. see Arundel, 2001; Cohen et al., 2000).
To provide a means of examining the relationship between the strength of trade secret protection in an
economy and that economy’s performance, the OECD developed an indicator of the stringency of
protection of trade secrets (the Trade Secrets Protection Index, or TSPI), which is presented in Chapter 3,
then updated and expanded in Chapter 4. Using a broad sample of OECD and non-OECD countries, the
TSPI reveals some similarities among them, notably with respect to the definition and scope of trade
secrets. However, it also shows that there are many, and more substantial, dissimilarities concerning the
implementation of protection for trade secrets. For example, differences are particularly pronounced in
evidence gathering and discovery, protection of trade secrets during litigation, technology transfer
requirements and the effectiveness of legal systems with respect to enforcement. That diversity is reflected
in the wide range of scores in the TSPI.
The overall index scores for 2010, the most recent year for which data are available, are shown in
Figure 11 below. OECD countries tend to have relatively high scores (reflecting stronger protection), while
Indonesia, Russia and the Philippines are all relatively low. The words “high” and “low” are not intended
to carry positive or negative connotations, though. The index’s function is descriptive, not normative, so
the scores it produces are neither grades nor ratings. Rather, the score is strictly an objective measure of the
stringency of protection.
Whereas Figure 1.11 provides a static view, or snapshot, of the TSPI in a particular year, Figure 12
provides a dynamic view over 20 years. The overall average TSPI score increased incrementally in each
period, but not all countries’ TSPI scores grew at the same rate. There is a significant gap between the
scores of the OECD economies and the trade partner countries in the sample. That gap has narrowed over
time, though it remains significant. The OECD economies’ scores gradually rose before stabilising in the
2005-2010 period. The average partner country scores, on the other hand, increased substantially following
the TRIPS Agreement in 1995.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
38 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.11.
Trade Secrets Protection Index, by Economy, 2010
Source: Derived from Chapter 4, Figure 4.1.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
39 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.12.
Trade Secrets Protection Index, Average Score by Country Group and Year
Trade Partner Countries (15)
OECD Economies (17)
4.50
4.00
3.50
3.00
2.50
2.00
1.50
1.00
0.50
0.00
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Note: This figure presents a balanced panel of economies in each group for which data were available in each of the years shown.
Inclusion in the OECD group is based on each country’s membership status as of 2010. Country coverage is as follows:
Trade partner economies: Argentina; Brazil; China; Chinese Taipei; Colombia; Ghana; Hong Kong, China; India; Indonesia; Malaysia;
Peru; Philippines; Singapore; South Africa; Thailand;
OECD countries: Australia; Canada; France; Germany; Ireland; Israel; Italy; Japan; Korea; Mexico; Netherlands; New Zealand; Spain;
Sweden; Turkey; United Kingdom; United States.
Source: Chapter 4, Figure 4.2.
The scores in Figures 1.11 and 1.12 are interesting in and of themselves, but the TSPI’s greatest value
is in what the scores make possible: an empirical examination of the effect of trade secret protection on
economic performance, including innovation. The variations in implementation of protection may
influence firm-level decision-making and may have implications for some aspects of economic
performance, especially innovation. Consequently, the development of the TSPI is a foundation for
studying the impact of the stringency of trade secret protection on economies.
Such quantitative work is all the more important because economic theory on the expected outcomes
from a strengthening of IP rights is inconclusive (Maskus, 2000; Primo Braga, 1990). Stronger rights may
motivate stakeholders to increase innovation and access to innovation, expanding markets to the benefit of
users as well as producers of IP. Even so, stronger rights might wind up creating or increasing market
power such that rights holders have an incentive to constrain access and/or retard further innovations,
possibly with little economic benefit to society as a whole. Therefore, empirical analysis is needed to test
the hypothesis that more stringent protection of trade secrets is associated with greater innovation and
diffusion. While such effects cannot be examined directly due to the lack of data, it is possible to study
(with standard regression analysis) whether changes in the TSPI are related to net changes in economic
indicators at an aggregate level while controlling for other factors.
That work is undertaken in Chapter 4, which uses an expanded time range, updated data, and a larger
sample of countries to assess the economic implications of variations in the TSPI. 43 While Chapter 4
avoids making policy recommendations, it does present policy-relevant findings based on countries’ actual
experiences with trade secrets protection. That information may help policy makers to identify and choose
among policy options for improved economic performance with respect to trade secrets. 44
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
40 | SYNTHESIS
The main conclusions of Chapter 4 are that 1) the TSPI scores vary significantly both among
countries at particular points in time, and within countries over time; 2) overall, the stringency of trade
secrets protection grew substantially in the sample countries between 1985 and 2010; and 3) there is a
positive and statistically significant relationship between the stringency of trade secret protection and
indicators of innovation inputs (including R&D expenditure and R&D personnel as a share of the labour
force) and international economic flows of investment and trade. (See Table 4.4 in Chapter 4.) Trade secret
protection may therefore have implications for domestic innovation, international technology transfer and
access to technology-intensive inputs and related products.
It must be stressed that what has been found is association, not necessarily causality. The results do
not mean that ever stronger protection, for example, will yield similar results. Nonetheless, the positive and
statistically significant relationships identified do indicate that adequately protecting trade secrets may be
an appropriate policy for supporting certain key aspects of economic performance. Taken together, the
information presented in Chapters 3 and 4 may assist policy makers in identifying options for using trade
secret laws and policies to improve economic performance.
Design rights
By improving aesthetic features such as shape, configuration, pattern, or ornament, designs make
products more appealing to consumers. Design rights therefore primarily concern the appearance of
products, rather than their technical features. When a design is protected, the owner receives an exclusive
right against unauthorised copying or imitation. In most countries, designs have to be registered to benefit
from protection under industrial design laws, but certain jurisdictions, such as the United Kingdom and the
European Union, also grant rights for unregistered designs (and those rights are typically more
limited 45). 46.
There is not a great deal of in-depth research available on the effect of design rights on economic
performance at the firm, industry, or economy-wide levels. However, there are indications that design
rights are becoming more important. Global design counts (the number of industrial designs contained in
applications) rebounded sharply after 2009 and reached an annual growth rate of 17 percent in 2012
(WIPO, 2013, p. 10). That corresponded to a total of 1.22 million designs filed worldwide. Much of the
growth was due to an increase in applications filed at the State Intellectual Property Office of the People’s
Republic of China. Approximately 2.7 million registered industrial designs are in force around the globe
(ibid). In the United Kingdom, Hargreaves (2011) not only characterised the design sector as important and
growing, but as already being the largest source of intangible investment in the economy. The global
growth of design rights will likely be strengthened by developments such as 3-D printing, which has the
potential to shift design infringement out of factories to anywhere there is a personal computer and a 3-D
printer.
To provide a closer look at the nature and economic impact of design and design rights, Chapter 6
explores the primary areas of design activity in a subset of 8 OECD countries plus the People’s Republic of
China, compares traits of design protection regimes in those economies, and reviews evidence on how
firms perceive the importance of design rights. It also surveys the literature on measures of design inputs
and outputs. The chapter is intended to be exploratory rather than comprehensive or conclusive. It should
therefore be considered as an initial step towards the possibility of a broader and deeper analysis of designrelated issues.
The chapter observes that measurement problems abound with respect to design. For example,
estimating the resources that go into developing designs is challenging because it is not entirely clear what
should count as designs and design-related activities. The word “design” is applied to activities that range
from engineering to art (Lawson, 2006). Designs can fulfil a number of different purposes that vary both
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
41 | SYNTHESIS
among and within firms. Designs in some firms are used only in connection with particular products, for
instance, whereas in other firms they play a part in entire processes. In fact, designs are sometimes not
directly related to developing a product or service, but concern something else such as corporate branding
(Walsh, 1996).
By looking at data on registered designs, however, it is possible to gain some understanding of the
types of products that attract the most investment in design IP. Figure 1.13 shows the top design categories
for each country in the sample used in Chapter 6, based on design filings at OHIM and at WIPO plus
national IP offices. As one would expect, given design rights’ focus on aesthetics, consumer goods are
most prominent in the figure.
Figure 1.13.
Top Two Design Application Fields, by Country, 2009-11
Source: Chapter 6, derived from OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2013, p. 187.
Although several international treaties affect design rights, such as the Paris Convention, the Berne
Convention and The Hague Agreement, Chapter 6 shows that there are nevertheless substantial differences
in the design rights frameworks of the sample countries. For example, the German and French laws place
relatively more emphasis on authors’ and inventors’ rights, and courts in those countries tend to be faster
and more proactive in protecting design rights. Furthermore, France’s Institut National de la Propriété
Industrielle has implemented a simplified procedure for registering designs. In Italy, the IP code contains a
special provision to cope with the problems related to the short life cycle of a product and the processing
time for the design application: the exclusive right takes effect from the date of filing the application, so
the design holder has the right to base a legal action from the filing application date in order to guarantee
effective protection in substantially disputed situations. Statistically, disputes on models and designs are
very frequently dealt with in summary or urgent proceedings characterised by faster decisions. In most
cases, the fast decision is not followed by an ordinary trial process.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
42 | SYNTHESIS
The procedures in France and Italy contrast with the situation in the United Kingdom, which appears
to be caught in a negative feedback loop regarding registered designs. UK inventors favour secrecy and
lead time over registered design rights for protecting their designs. But relying on lead time tends to cause
shorter product cycles which, in turn, make it less worthwhile to undertake the burdensome application
process for registering designs. Consequently, relying on secrecy and lead time instead becomes even more
attractive. The result is the comparatively low rate of design registration in the UK that we saw earlier in
Table 2, UK Market Sector Investment in Tangibles, Intangibles, and IPRs (see also Chapter 6, citing BOP
Consulting, 2011).
Looking at trends in OHIM design applications and OHIM registered designs among the nine
countries studied in Chapter 6, we can see in Figure 1.14 that applications from most countries gradually
increased over the past ten years. 47 During the same period, the total number of designs registered with
OHIM from the leading countries of origin (Germany, Italy, France, US) grew at first, then levelled off or
even dipped (Figure 1.15). Note, however, the substantial growth in registered designs from the People’s
Republic of China and Korea.
Figure 1.14.
OHIM Design Applications by Country of Origin
Source: Chapter 6, Figure 6.5.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
43 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.15.
OHIM Registered Designs by Country of Origin
Source: Chapter 6, Figure 6.6.
While the two figures immediately above provide an indication of the relative magnitudes of design
activity in the sample countries, it is difficult to draw from them a clear impression of which countries are
relatively more and less design-intensive, given the fact that the countries vary so much in population and
GDP. Figure 1.16 offers a perspective on design activity that is normalised on a per capita basis.
Figure 1.16.
Combined OHIM and USPTO Design Stocks by Country of Origin per Million Inhabitants
Source: Chapter 6, Figure 6.9.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
44 | SYNTHESIS
Now we can see that Germany has led consistently since 2004 in registered design output per capita,
with the US not far behind. Meanwhile, Korea experienced the strongest growth. (China’s normalised trend
remains very low throughout the period due to the size of its population.)
Chapter 6 also surveys the literature and summarises the qualitative and quantitative methods used to
measure resources devoted to design at the firm level (see Chapter 6, for more detail). The methods range
from a binary inquiry on whether there is an aesthetic design group within the firm to surveys that request
estimates on design spending. Likewise, the chapter includes summaries of the methods used in the
literature for correlating design inputs with various outputs (see Chapter 6). For example, the methods
include correlating design inputs with sales growth, profit margins, and stock market performance.
Most of the studies do not focus on design IP, but rather on design activity in general. However, one
study did isolate the impact of design IP, and the results showed that they have a weak effect. While
eighty-five percent of the UK businesses surveyed by The Design Council (2009) indicated that design was
a significant part of their business model, 66 percent did nothing to protect their IP (regardless of whether
it was a design or something else). A mere four percent used registered designs. Another four per cent used
unregistered designs. That means not even ten percent of the businesses that consider design important use
formal design protection measures. 48
Why is firm reliance on design IP so low, at least in the UK? The answer may have something to do
with the administrative burden of filing coupled with the brief commercial lifespan of many designs,
mentioned earlier. But that cannot explain the fact that firms do not rely much on unregistered design
rights, either. Moreover, in an earlier study, The Design Council (2005) found that companies that were
“effective users of design” outperformed the UK stock market by 200 percent between 1994 and 2004. 49
Notably, the study determined which firms used designs effectively not by looking at whether or how they
used design IP, but primarily by looking at which firms were nominated for and won design awards. Their
financial performance, combined with what we know about how few of them are using design IP, leads to
several questions. Are design rights necessary? What motivation do they provide for investing in designrelated KBC? Should the framework be changed to make design rights more meaningful? The UK studies
notwithstanding, though, Chapter 6 also shows that there has been, overall, a modest rise in registered
designs among the sample countries, so those questions can be answered confidently only with the help of
more studies, both within and outside of the UK.
How Internet Growth and Digitisation Are Affecting Stakeholders and IP Systems
The growth of the Internet in terms of traffic, bandwidth, and reach, in combination with digitisation,
has had considerable effects on IP owners, consumers, and intermediaries, as well as on IP laws and the
enforcement of those laws. Those effects have been significant enough that some commentators have gone
so far as to argue that IP laws are no longer relevant or necessary in the Internet era. That, however, is not a
consensus view. In fact, the OECD Council has stated that “effective protection of intellectual property
rights plays a vital role in spurring innovation and furthers the development of the Internet economy”
(OECD, 2011).
With that in mind, consider Figure 1.17, which illustrates how digitisation and then the Internet have
changed the ways in which people access, listen to and pay for copyrighted content– in this case, music in
the United Kingdom. It also captures the waves of innovation that brought one technological improvement
after another to this sector.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
45 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.17.
Singles
The Evolution of Music Sales in the United Kingdom, by Format, 1972-2012
LP
Cassette
CD
8 Track
Music Video
Digital Tracks
Digital Albums
Other Digital
£1.4
Phase I
(up to 1983)
‘Physical Analogue’
Phase II
(1984-2002)
‘Physical Digital’
Phase III
(2003-2006)
‘Online Download’
Phase IV
(2007-)
‘Online Streaming’
£1.2
Music sales, bn
£1.0
£0.8
£0.6
£0.4
£0.2
£0.0
72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12
Source: BPI (2013).
Such changes, while carrying forward a wave of new and innovative business models, do not
necessarily translate into profits, net gains for economies, greater productivity or greater consumer surplus,
at least not immediately. The adoption of new technologies can take time. In the music sector, what online
digital downloads did to CDs, streaming is now doing to downloads. According to data from a North
American music sales tracking system, 2013 was the first year since Apple’s iTunes store launched in 2003
that digital download sales declined. Streaming services, meanwhile, are growing (Bond, 2014), but
revenues from streaming are still well below download and CD sales. Consequently, in the United
Kingdom at least, as Figure 1.17 above shows, total revenues across all music formats were falling through
2012. That is not due to changing formats alone (though it may be true that customers spend less on
average when they stream or download than they did when they bought CDs). The major culprit is likely to
be piracy, which was greatly enabled by digital technologies. It is, however, difficult to obtain accurate and
objective data on the precise magnitude of piracy that is taking place. 50 Furthermore, other factors may
have contributed to a decline in sales, too, such as demographic shifts and increased competition (OECD,
2005).
In any event, although the declining revenues have raised questions about whether artists and some
music labels can make enough money from streaming to survive, streaming models are still evolving and
growing. Indeed, as IFPI points out, “The music business continues to expand into new markets and create
new business models, attracting more users to digital music services and bringing artists to a wider global
audience.” 51 While global recorded music revenues fell 3.9 percent in 2013, there are signs that the decline
is stabilising. Recorded music revenues in Europe and Latin America grew 0.8 percent in 2013. 52
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
46 | SYNTHESIS
Moreover, the number of customers who pay for music streaming in the United States rose from 8 million
in 2010 to 28 million in 2013 (Bond, 2014), and Spotify’s paid subscriber base climbed from 12.5 million
to 15 million during the last two months of 2014 alone (Cookson, 2015).
Chapter 5 of this Report provides a broader overview of some of the new business models that have
been enabled by digitisation and the Internet. Some models, such as streaming film and television
programming services and MMOG (massively multiplayer online game) services, use advances in digital
technology to deliver content in new ways. Other types of businesses, such as e-reader device makers and
developers of game apps for mobile phones, take advantage of the portability offered by the mobile
Internet. Still others, again including the mobile game app developers but also businesses such as Spotify
and Netflix, use business models that rely on web-based ads or subscriptions to generate revenue rather
than unit sales.
Some of these new business models have brought very substantial benefits to consumers and have
accordingly been rewarded with great financial success. Apple’s iTunes Store, for example, is available in
119 countries and puts more than 26 million songs at the disposal of its customers. A music selection of
that size would be impossible in a physical media, bricks-and-mortar retail store format. The iTunes Store
also contributes to the popularity of iPhones, iPods and iPads. Apple’s market value has soared as a result,
eclipsing the value of some major countries’ entire stock markets (Trotman, 2014). As Chapter 5 further
points out, Facebook users have shared some 250 billion photos on the platform, while 100 hours of video
are uploaded for sharing on YouTube every minute.
Another effect of digitisation and Internet growth is that it has led several countries to adjust their
copyright laws. For example, some countries have implemented exceptions for temporary copying because
Internet use would be severely impeded without them. One has added an exception for text and data
mining (which would not be possible without digitisation) while several have implemented exceptions for
cloud computing.
Chapter 5 reports on the legal settings and mainstream policy dialogues in 12 diverse jurisdictions,
noting that all of them have amended, or are considering amending, their copyright exemption frameworks
in light of the changes brought on by digitisation and the Internet. For example, the United Kingdom
recently amended its copyright law to introduce a specific exception that allows text and data mining for
non-commercial research purposes without the right holder’s prior authorisation. In contrast, legislators in
some countries, such as Israel and the United States, do not necessarily have to consider amending their
laws every time there is a significant technological change that affects copyright. That is because their laws
include an open norm for considering new unlicensed uses. It is left to the courts to determine whether a
particular use qualifies as an exception or not, consistent with national laws and international treaty
obligations. Because technology is constantly developing, certain other countries have considered, or are
considering, adopting open norms, too. See Box 1.3.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
47 | SYNTHESIS
Box 1.3
•
•
•
•
•
Open Norms in Effect or Under Consideration in Some OECD Countries
The United States has had a flexible standard for copyright exceptions for many years. The “fair use”
doctrine was originally developed by the courts and then codified in § 107 of the Copyright Act (1976). The
doctrine is characterised by an open-ended list of purposes for which the use of a work may be regarded as
fair, and by four factors to be considered in determining whether other particular uses are fair: 1) the
purpose and character of the use, including whether such use is of a commercial nature or is for non-profit
educational purposes; 2) the nature of the copyrighted work; 3) the amount and substantiality of the portion
used in relation to the copyrighted work as a whole; and 4) the effect of the use upon the potential market
for or value of the copyrighted work.
Article 19 of Israel’s Copyright Act of 2007 contains an open-ended fair use defence that can be invoked in a
wide variety of cases and situations. The article is modelled after section 107 of the United States’ Copyright
Act (1976).
Canadian law contains a flexible fair dealing exception that was updated in 2012. It is now considered by
some commentators to be comparable to the United States’ fair use doctrine (Geist, 2013, at 157-86).
Australia has a fair dealing exception, but the courts have interpreted it less broadly than United States and
Canadian courts have interpreted the fair use and fair dealing exceptions, respectively, in effect there. The
Australian Law Reform Commission recently considered whether exceptions and statutory licences in the
Copyright Act 1968 are suitable in the digital environment and whether further exceptions should be
recommended. In its Final Report (Australian Law Reform Commission, 2014), the ALRC examined the
comparative pros and cons of introducing a fair use defence or amending the fair dealing defence. It
recommended that Parliament introduce a fair use exception.
The Netherlands commissioned a study that considered the law and economics of adding an open norm to
its copyright law in 2012 (van der Noll, 2012). However, the Dutch Government has not indicated any action
to implement the recommendations in the Report.
Some countries have also adjusted their copyright frameworks in light of the higher incidence of
piracy that digitisation and the Internet have enabled. For instance, Korea and the United Kingdom have
introduced special police units to combat online piracy. Italy and the United States have passed new laws
that make it possible to block websites that host copyright-infringing content.
There have also been some controversial legislative reactions to the impact of the Internet and
digitisation on established copyright owners. Several countries have enacted or proposed amendments to
their copyright laws 53 that create an ancillary copyright to the benefit of online publishers. The result is that
certain material used by Internet-based news aggregating services could be infringing.
For example, Spain’s law 54 imposes a compulsory license whenever a web site provides even a small
fragment of a newspaper article. It also requires permission from the news publisher for the reuse of any
photo posted to a periodically updated website. Spain’s competition authority quickly criticised the law
when it was proposed (Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia, 2014). It noted that the main
justification given for the proposal is to compensate the original news sites with “fair compensation” for
the “direct competition” that occurs between them and the news aggregators, who do not share the costs
that the “creative effort” entails. However, the competition authority found it questionable that there was
any such direct competition, that any compensation was appropriate, or if there was, that it should flow
toward the original sites. The latter is finding recognised that appearing in news aggregator results will
drive more Internet traffic toward the original site than it would otherwise get. The authority also noted
that the law would create a barrier to access for companies that want to enter the market for content
aggregation.
Of course, copyright is not the only form of KBC protection that is affected by the rise of digital
technologies and the Internet. Just as those factors facilitated piracy, for instance, they also made it easier
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
48 | SYNTHESIS
for company insiders and third parties to disseminate trade secrets rapidly (and not necessarily legally, as
hacking and industrial espionage were also facilitated). Moreover, digital technologies like 3-D printing, in
combination with the Internet, may greatly facilitate design rights infringement by eliminating the need for
a traditional factory to produce goods using infringing designs; instead, all that will be needed is an
Internet connection, a computer, and a 3-D printer.
With respect to patents, digitisation and the Internet have made it easier to access, search and sort the
information contained in patents and that has unquestionably improved dissemination of that knowledge.
This not only helps the public, but possibly patent examiners, too. Consequently, it might improve the
quality of the patent examination process and therefore of the patents themselves. As patent offices digitise
their patent literature, put more of it in searchable databases, and make those databases available on the
Internet, it becomes easier for the public and patent examiners to search for, find, and determine what the
prior art is. On the other hand, though, the Internet makes it easier to advertise and sell infringing items
like counterfeit pharmaceuticals.
The Internet and digitisation have also opened up new opportunities to organise and publish the
content of research projects, scientific publications and large data sets, so as to make them immediately
available to other scientists, researchers, and potential users in the business community and society in
general. In addition, digital technologies allow the collection of large amounts of data that can be the basis
of scientific experiments and research, helping to make science increasingly data-driven. Consequently, it
is now technologically possible to access, use and re-use research, articles and datasets at no or extremely
low marginal cost and speed the transfer of knowledge amongst researchers and across scientific fields.
That, in turn, can lead to new ways of collaboration and new research domains. However, publishing high
quality, peer-reviewed scientific articles in reputable journals, and making that information available
online in an organised, reliable and searchable manner, comes at a cost. Someone has to pay, even when
the research itself is publicly funded, and the ability to recoup costs is part of what copyright facilitates.
The interplay between copyright and open access to publicly funded research results is further discussed
later in this chapter.
The net overall effects on an economy from Internet growth and digitisation are hard to disentangle
from other factors, such as the recession that began in 2008. New Internet-based business models are
adding to the recession’s impact on older firms by helping to push them out of the market, but at the same
time those new firms are generating jobs. The traditional publishing sector in the United States, for
example – bookstores, printers, newspaper and magazine publishers – has shed 400,000 jobs since 2008.
During the same time, Internet publishers and web search firms added 76,000 jobs. Clearly that is
preferable to a loss of 400,000 jobs with no offsetting gains, but it is hard to know how many publishing
jobs were lost due to the Internet firms’ entry as opposed to the recession or other factors. Trying to figure
out how consumers have fared while adjusting to these changes adds another layer of complexity. This
much is clear, though: the Internet publishing and search salaries are nearly twice as high, on average, as
the newspaper publishing salaries (about USD 80,000 versus USD 46,000). 55
The Merits and Means of Open Access to Publicly Funded Research Results
Internet growth and digitisation, along with advances in “big data” and data analytics (see the other
phase 2 report, Data-Driven Innovation for Growth and Well-Being), have also affected the ways in which
publicly funded research results are accessed, disseminated and used. Digital technology is unquestionably
bringing more and more possibilities to create, read, share, use and re-use scientific articles and data. That
information is often covered by IP laws. 56 Open access (OA) principles, which aim to make the outputs 57
of publicly funded research more widely accessible and available for copying, use, re-use and further
distribution in digital formats (while preserving authors’ rights to control the integrity of their work and to
be credited) 58, therefore raise a number of IP-related questions. One of the most important is how to define
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
49 | SYNTHESIS
research exceptions for protected material. (Open Access is explored in detail in Chapter 7, Legal Aspects
of Open Access to Publicly Funded Research.)
The significance of such questions should not be underestimated. Scientific research is vital to solving
global challenges such as climate change, disease, and security issues. Access to research data not only
increases the returns from public investment in confronting those challenges, but it also reinforces open
scientific inquiry, encourages diversity of thought, allows a more accurate validation of research results,
and leads to the advancement of knowledge in new fields (OECD, 2014). Prompt and cost efficient access
to publicly-funded scientific research therefore promotes general economic and social welfare (OECD,
2007; European Commission, 2007). Furthermore, to the extent that OA leads to greater collaboration
among researchers from different institutions and countries, it can also lead to outputs that have a stronger
influence in their field. Figure 1.18 shows that there is a positive association between international
collaboration and the impact of scientific publications:
Figure 1.18.
The Impact of Scientific Production and the Extent of International Scientific Collaboration,
2003-11
Note: Whole counts of internationally co-authored documents. The normalised impact is derived as the ratio between the average
number of citations received by the documents published by authors affiliated to an institution in a given economy and the world
average of citations, over the same time period, by document type and subject area. The international institutional collaboration
indicator is based on the proportion of documents involving institutional affiliations with other countries or economies, as a proportion
of documents attributed to authors with an affiliation in the reference economy. Single-authored documents with multiple affiliations
across boundaries can therefore count as institutional international collaboration.
Source: OECD, 2013c, p. 60; data available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932890314.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
50 | SYNTHESIS
Box 1.4 sets out more information about the benefits that open access to publicly funded research
results can offer for research and innovation.
Box 1.4
•
•
•
•
•
•
Rationales for Open Access to Publicly Funded Research
Improved efficiency in science: OA can increase the effectiveness and the productivity of the research
system by: 1) reducing duplication and costs of creating, transferring and re-using data; 2) allowing more
research from the same data; 3) multiplying opportunities for domestic and global participation in the
research process;
Increased transparency and quality in the research validation process, by allowing replication and validation
of scientific results to a greater extent;
Faster knowledge transfer: OA can reduce delays in the publication of articles and data sets and accelerate
the progression from research to innovation;
More knowledge spillovers to the economy: better access to the results of publicly funded research can
foster spillovers and boost innovation across the economy. The disclosure and release of public and
scientific data may promote the development of innovative products and services in firms as well as
increase awareness and conscious choices among consumers;
Greater effectiveness in overcoming global challenges: global challenges call for co-ordinated international
actions. OA may promote collaborative efforts and faster knowledge transfer, leading to better
understanding and potentially to the identification of solutions for challenges such as climate change and
ageing populations;
More engagement by citizens in science and research: OA initiatives may promote awareness and trust in
science among citizens. In some cases, greater citizens’ engagement leads to participation in scientific
experiments and data collection.
Source: OECD, 2013e; European Commission, 2012a.
Accordingly, OA principles have been viewed with increasing favour by some policy makers,
research funding agencies, higher education institutions and researchers. Sometimes that favour is reflected
in generally applicable laws and sometimes in the policies of individual organisations. Furthermore, the
measures taken do not always reflect all OA principles, e.g. they might cover only access and not
reproduction or re-use (OECD, 2014c).
OA initiatives undertaken in Europe and the United States will be summarised presently, but first it is
useful to briefly explain the two main ways in which OA principles can be put into action. One, known as
the “Golden Road”, requires authors to pay the cost of publishing their publicly funded outputs in journals
that provide free open access. The other, called the “Green Road”, permits authors to publish their publicly
funded works via traditional channels but requires the authors to self-archive and to provide access to those
works by making their own e-prints free for everyone. The Golden Road is considered preferable by OA
advocates because it tends to entail fewer restrictions on authors. That is because authors are more likely to
retain only limited rights when they publish in traditional, non-OA subscription journals. Therefore selfarchived, Green Road articles typically come with a licence that restricts what readers can do with the
material. Moreover, it is not necessarily easy for readers to determine from the licenses what those
restrictions are (see Chapter 7, Guibault, 2011, at 137-167).
The European Commission is in the process of implementing OA principles, which are reflected in its
model grant agreement for the Horizon 2020 research programme. The Commission is promoting OA not
only for scientific publications, but for their underlying data. Accordingly, the model agreement requires
recipients to deposit the data and associated metadata that are necessary to validate published results (as
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
51 | SYNTHESIS
well as the scientific publications themselves) in a research data depository and to take measures that allow
third parties to access, mine, exploit, reproduce and disseminate that data at no charge. However, the
Horizon 2020 OA policy is not binding on Member States, which leaves Europe with a number of
inconsistent national OA policies instead of one consistent policy. The spectrum of approaches includes,
for example, a mandatory Golden Road for publications and data (Research Councils of the United
Kingdom) and a Green Road for publications only (Germany) (Chapter 7).
In the United States, a White House Directive requires all federal agencies that spend more than USD
100 million on research and development to come up with plans to make the published results of their
federally funded R&D freely available to the public. It directs agencies to use a 12-month post-publication
embargo period as a guideline for making research papers publicly available. 59 There is also a pending bill,
the Fair Access to Science and Technology Research (FASTR) Act, which is similar to the Directive but
cuts the embargo period to six months and would carry the weight of a statute. The Directive expressly
states that each affected agency’s “plans must also describe, to the extent feasible, procedures the agency
will take to help prevent the unauthorised mass redistribution of scholarly publications.” In other words,
the agencies must ensure access, but they should also try to restrict copying and sharing. FASTR,
meanwhile, mandates Green Road OA but says nothing about Golden Road OA. See Chapter 7 of this
Report for more information on the relevant aspects of IP regimes and OA approaches in a sample of
jurisdictions.
UNESCO (2012) has, incidentally, issued Policy Guidelines for the Development and Promotion of
Open Access that explain what OA is and provide practical steps for governments, institutions and funding
agencies that wish to put OA policies in place. The guidelines are not prescriptive, but rather aim to
promote OA by facilitating more knowledgeable decisions to adopt OA policies and strengthen national
research systems.
One way to gauge the actual impact of OA is to compare the number of citations that OA publications
receive with the number received by non-OA publications. The academic literature contains several studies
that make such comparisons (e.g. UNESCO, 2012; Swan, 2010; Wagner, 2010; OpCit Project, 2012). Most
of them demonstrate that OA has the effect of increasing citations. However, there is no consensus on the
intensity of that increase. A minority of the studies do not show any citation advantage at all for OA
publications (Davis et al., 2008; Fradsen, 2009; Lansingh & Carter, 2009).
Academics are not the only groups that can potentially benefit from greater OA, though. The demand
from the business sector and individual citizens to access research results is significant. For example, the
usage data from PubMedCentral (the online repository of the United States National Institutes of Health,
where an OA policy is in effect) show that 25 percent of the daily unique users are from universities, but
17 percent are from companies, 40 percent are individual citizens and the rest are from government or
other categories (UNESCO, 2012).
Chapter 7 of this Report explores the interplay between OA policies and IP laws in a sample of
jurisdictions, reaching a number of conclusions and raising several questions:
•
The explosive growth in data volumes will probably not make copyright protection either more or
less relevant than it is now, provided that the criteria for copyright protection are applied strictly
(either in the form of an ‘originality’ requirement or that of being an ‘author’s own intellectual
creation’).
•
However, in countries with laws that protect databases, the growth in data may bring about a
trend towards private appropriation of databases. If that happens, applying OA principles to
publicly-funded scientific output will become more important.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
52 | SYNTHESIS
•
The increase of machine-generated data in science (e.g. scientific sensors) may raise certain
challenges, especially the question of whether such data meet the criteria for IP protection.
•
A related challenge might be the use of machine-generated data to identify rights owners. Ideally,
the machine-generated data will not qualify as protectable subject matter so that it will in
principle be free for everyone to use for the purpose of identifying rights owners.
•
Another concern is the lack of clarity in national or supra-national legal frameworks. Legal
frameworks are being adapted to promote OA in several jurisdictions. Researchers and scientists
need to understand exactly what is allowed and forbidden in order to make legitimate use of OA.
The frameworks are not always easy to navigate, though. For example, the European Union’s
Information Society Directive gives copyright owners the exclusive right to reproduce their
works, communicate them to the public and distribute them. Notably, the Directive allows
Member States to make an exception for situations in which a protected work is used for the
purpose of illustration for teaching or scientific research. However, the exception is optional, and
that has led not only to varying approaches from country to country within the EU but to
vagueness, because there is no single, clear standard even among the countries that have
implemented the exception (Guibault, 2010, at 55-66; Triaille, 2014, at 403).
•
An unresolved issue is how the ownership of rights to articles and data, as well as the applicable
licensing terms, affect OA when the research is funded by public/private partnerships. When
governments partner with external organisations on research projects, the ownership of the
resulting outputs is regulated by contract. Depending on a number of factors – the law, relative
bargaining power, the organisation’s policies – copyright ownership may wind up entirely in the
hands of the external partner. The author rarely retains it, but who owns the rights greatly affects
how the outputs will be published – traditional channels, Green Road OA, or Golden Road OA.
While an objective of OA is to make access and use of publicly funded articles and data cost-free to
users, doing so is not costless. Someone still has to pay to support peer reviews, the publishing process,
archiving, etc., and it is often the authors who pay. However, many agencies in countries that implement
OA policies are setting aside funding to help researchers at institutions meet mandates for OA publishing.
Smaller countries, smaller institutions and academic societies, though, may face additional funding
hurdles.
Meanwhile, the private sector is making progress with OA initiatives. Initially threatened by OA
publishing, scientific publishers are now developing business models of their own for OA and offering new
data curation and storage services. Moreover, new research data start-ups are challenging established
publishers, creating pressure to innovate in the publishing sector (see Chapter 7, “Promoting a New Era of
Scientific Discovery”, DSTI/ICCP(2014)16/CHAP8, in the other phase 2 report, Data Driven Innovation
for Growth and Well-Being).
It is critical for OA initiatives to achieve a good balance between openness and protection/control, so
as to promote sharing without reducing the incentives to conduct research and compete. For example, OA
to scientific publications may not necessarily involve access to data and the associated right of use and reuse and vice-versa. Free licensing solutions, such as the Creative Commons 4.0 licence 60, are available and
enhance openness in data without the loss of control over ownership.
Consumer Protection and Copyright in the Digital Era
Because digital content products are often subject to copyright protection, the OECD Committee on
Consumer Policy’s work in establishing policy guidance for digital content products adds another
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
53 | SYNTHESIS
dimension to the broader discussion on the impact that copyright systems are having and how they are
functioning in the digital era. The Committee on Consumer Policy examined trends and consumer policy
challenges in the acquisition and use of digital content products, focusing on those that consumers store,
access or receive in an electronic (i.e. intangible) format. That resulted in an analytic report (OECD 2013d)
and ultimately policy guidance (OECD 2014e) which recommends that consumers be provided with clear
and conspicuous information about functionality, interoperability and geographic limitations, and with
effective protection against misleading or unfair commercial practices.
With the spread of broadband, easy-to-use mobile devices and online and mobile payments, products
such as books, music, films, videos and games are increasingly supplied and acquired by consumers in an
electronic format via the Internet and other ICT channels (such as mobile operators’ networks) through
streaming, downloading or cloud computing platforms. While such technological advances are providing
consumers with many new possibilities to legitimately copy, share, transform and transfer a wide range of
high quality intangible digital content products, their ability to do so is often limited by: i) copyright laws;
ii) the terms and conditions in end-user licensing agreements (EULAs); iii ) other terms of service
provisions; and iv) technical measures (commonly referred to as “digital rights management” [DRM]) that
limit or prevent product access and usage across the consumer’s devices.
Such limitations can vary significantly from one product to another. For example, the period over
which a consumer may be able to use a product may be limited or indefinite; the number of times a product
(such as a piece of music or an e-book) can be accessed, streamed or downloaded may be limited; and
there may be conditions or limitations for sharing a product with others, including friends or family
members. Further, consumers may be unable to play, listen, or watch a product on different devices.
Moreover, consumers may not always be able to access a product that they have acquired in one
jurisdiction while travelling in another; they may be unable to acquire an intangible digital content product
offered by businesses located in other jurisdictions. The latter limitations are, in many instances, due to
geographical licensing restrictions or other specific limitations placed on products by suppliers. 61 There are
market incentives to overcome these challenges, but solutions have not yet been created and implemented
in all markets.
Surveys reveal that a vast majority of consumers are often unaware of the limitations just mentioned
and generally expect to enjoy the same rights with digital content products that they have with physical
goods. This is partly due to the fact that consumers are often unsure about what is permitted under existing
copyright law and how the law applies in different circumstances. 62 Moreover, consumers tend not to read
EULAs, which often contain complex and lengthy terms and conditions that are not always easily
accessible prior to making a purchase (European Commission, 2011).
A number of misleading commercial practices have been reported. These practices include, for
example, businesses’ failure to provide conspicuous, adequate and timely information to consumers about
product access and usage, and suppliers pushing product updates without prior notification (Europe
Economics, 2011).
Knowledge Diffusion from Patents and Trade Secrets
Among the benefits that IP rights bring to economies is their ability to stimulate knowledge diffusion.
Whether it occurs via a disclosure requirement in an application process, through a licensing agreement, or
by way of a partnership arrangement bound by confidentiality agreements, knowledge diffusion is
facilitated by IP. In this section we will explore and compare the diffusion effects from patents and trade
secrets. As we will see, inventors sometimes have a choice between these two forms of protection, so it can
be interesting to examine what drives their decisions and what the resulting effects on diffusion are.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
54 | SYNTHESIS
Note that diffusion depends on more than just disclosure. It requires dissemination, too. Thus, in the
context of the patent system, for example, diffusion requires more than just the act of providing
information in a patent application. It also depends on that information being made available to the public,
and on the public accessing and using that information.
It is also important to bear in mind that IP covers a huge variety of KBC. That can lead to some
special, and perhaps counterintuitive, situations. For example, the greater knowledge diffusion that results
from patents is generally assumed to be a desirable effect because it enables further innovation. There are
circumstances, though, when society may at least arguably be better off if proprietary knowledge remains
out of the public’s reach. Consider a recent case: calls for Google to make its search engine algorithm
transparent so that greater competition might be stimulated in European Internet search and advertising
markets (Vasagar & Fontanella-Khan, 2014). Although the functional core of Google’s algorithm has been
known for years (Brin & Page, 1998; Page, et al. 1999), certain aspects of the algorithm are held as trade
secrets. Some of them are designed to thwart search engine optimisers, which are services that aim to boost
a site’s rank in search results by attempting to understand a search engine’s methods and manipulate them
to distort the results in a client’s favour. Critics of the idea that Google should be required to disclose its
full algorithm contend that the result would not only be bad for Google, but for everyone. The optimisers
would obtain complete knowledge of how the algorithm works, and with that information in their hands,
Google’s search results would soon become distorted and unreliable (McGeer, 2014; Pasquale, 2010, at
350; Grimmelmann, 2010, at 454).
There are undoubtedly several other exceptional situations in which knowledge diffusion would
probably be harmful to society. Information about how to build bioweapons or other weapons of mass
destruction, for example, comes to mind.
Patent disclosure and diffusion
The disclosure requirement is a key component of the exchange built into the patent system: in
principle, exclusivity is granted to inventors during the short and medium term while the information
disclosure facilitates knowledge diffusion and more innovation in the medium and longer term. In essence,
patent disclosure requirements call for information that is sufficient to enable a person skilled in the art to
replicate the invention. But a wide array of other information can be found in patent applications, too.
Beyond the technical information, there is legal and business information. That makes patent information
potentially useful to different audiences for different purposes. Researchers, potential licensees,
competitors, policy makers, and patent examiners may all find helpful information in patents applications.
It is not clear that disclosure is a very effective means of diffusing knowledge in practice, though.
Empirical results vary from sector to sector and by firm size, but the overall extent to which reading
patents promotes follow-on innovation is not known. There is also some evidence that the quality of
disclosure is inadequate in some instances (Chapter 8). In one study, Ouellette (2012) surveyed about 200
nanotechnologists. Sixty-four percent of the respondents had read a patent, and 60 percent of those who
had read patents for scientific (i.e. non-legal) reasons said that they had found useful technical information.
Accordingly, the survey indicates that patent disclosures are certainly not useless, insofar as some
scientists get some value from the information disclosed.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
55 | SYNTHESIS
Figure 1.19.
Responses of Nanotechnologists to Questions about Patent Disclosures (% positive)
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
had read a
patent
looked for
technical
information
found
information
useful
believed
technology
reproducible
Source: Ouellette (2012).
However, 36 percent of respondents had never read a patent and 40 percent of those who had read a
patent for technical reasons did not find any useful information. Furthermore, 62 percent of the patent
readers thought that the patents they read did not provide sufficient disclosure for a nanotech researcher to
recreate the invention. Ouellette’s work suggests that the quality of disclosure could be significantly
improved and casts doubt on whether the existing ‘enablement’ requirements are meaningful. Fromer
(2009, at 560) notes that “a good deal of evidence suggests that technologists do not find [that patents]
contain[] pertinent information for their research.”
Another problem is that certain strategic behaviours by patentees can degrade knowledge diffusion.
For example, so-called “thesaurus patents” are applications that have been drafted in ways that make it
harder to understand the invention, or even simply to discover it through a computerised word search in the
first place. Furthermore, applicants have an incentive to disclose no more about how to reproduce the
invention than the bare minimum required by the law. 63
But it is critical that disclosures are as useful as lawmakers intended them to be. We have seen that
intangible assets are becoming an ever-more important component of OECD economies. And we will see
in section 3.6 that IP is becoming an increasingly important source of financing for SMEs, which generate
a disproportionate share of job growth. Those financing markets, like all markets, depend on information to
function well. “It is crucial that patent data is seriously useful in order to make markets work. If intangible
capital is the foundation of the economy for the next century, then it is necessary to have a wellfunctioning information system in place: hiding such vitally important data will not help progress”
(Chapter 8, paraphrasing remarks by Tony Clayton).
A counterbalancing factor is that digitisation and the growth of the Internet have been especially
beneficial for the dissemination aspect of diffusion. By digitising their application processes and putting
databases of their patent information online, patent offices around the world have made substantial
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
56 | SYNTHESIS
progress in improving access to patent information (Chapter 8). Not only that, but the information can be
obtained faster, more affordably, and it is searchable, as well. By encouraging and funding these efforts by
patent offices, governments can help to ensure that economies are getting the maximum amount of
knowledge diffusion from their patent systems. 64
Several other ideas for improving the utility of patent disclosures emerged at the expert workshop
held in connection with this report (Chapter 8). One recommended approach is simply to put more effort
into applying the disclosure laws that we already have. Greater time and resources could be devoted to
scrutinising the adequacy of disclosure during the patent examination stage, to ensure that, for instance, the
patented technology is reproducible by a person skilled in the art. In addition, a peer review system might
be helpful because, although patent examiners have scientific backgrounds, it is difficult for anyone to be
skilled in every area. Another possibility concerns the lag between the date of filing and the date of
publication (when disclosure occurs). That lag can be considerable, and may seem even longer in fastmoving fields. Reducing the lag, at least in some technology areas, could make disclosures more useful by
ensuring that the information is still fresh.
Trade secrets and diffusion, and a comparison with diffusion from patents
It may seem counterintuitive, but some knowledge diffusion may be expected to result from trade
secret protection. Trade secrets are confidential, but they are commercial, too. The laws therefore anticipate
and accommodate a certain degree of protected disclosure. By providing a legal framework for
safeguarding firms’ valuable and secret information, including remedial measures in case of a breach, laws
covering trade secrets can give firms the confidence and security they need to collaborate more closely
with business partners. Thus, trade secrets owners are sometimes willing to share sensitive knowledge with
other firms (subject to licensing and/or confidentiality agreements). Moreover, when employees switch
jobs, even though non-compete agreements may limit the amount of information they can share with their
next employer, the employees may be able to share some useful know-how that is related to the trade
secrets but is not actually part of them (Lemley, 2011).
In principle, however, one might expect a smaller diffusion effect from trade secrets than from
patents. Patents require the invention to be disclosed to the public, whereas trade secrets protection is
premised on keeping the invention secret (or sharing it, at most, only with business partners that are subject
to confidentiality agreements). In addition, patents eventually expire, putting the invention they once
protected into the public domain. Trade secrets, on the contrary, can endure indefinitely. Although trade
secret laws do not prohibit reverse engineering, firms are unlikely to rely on trade secret protection for
their valuable knowledge if it is easy to reverse-engineer and if they can choose patent protection instead.65
Finally, the diffusion effect associated with patents can stem from both licensing agreements and the
disclosure requirement in the application process, whereas there is obviously no disclosure requirement for
trade secrets.
On the other hand, it has been discussed already that patent disclosures are not necessarily optimal.
Furthermore, patent protection might be used in combination with trade secret protection in a manner that
inhibits the beneficial effects of disclosure requirements. For example, if even a person skilled in the
relevant discipline would be unable to reproduce an invention despite having all of the patent
documentation at hand, e.g. because the inventor has revealed the absolute minimum necessary to obtain
the patent but has kept some crucial know-how secret, then the owner has essentially bundled patent
protection with trade secret protection. That strategy, if successful, would obviously restrict the intended
benefits of the patent disclosure system. Nevertheless, it seems difficult to conclude that patents’ average
knowledge diffusion effect is smaller than that of trade secrets.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
57 | SYNTHESIS
This point is theoretical, though – and it must remain theoretical – because empirical data on trade
secrets is scarce due to their non-public nature. We simply cannot know the number or value of trade
secrets in an economy, how long they have existed, or how much knowledge they diffuse, because they are
hidden from public view. What we do know is that firms generally say they rely more on secrecy than on
patents (though in certain sectors, like pharmaceuticals, the opposite is true), 66 and there is evidence that
the main reason businesses use trade secrets instead of other forms of IP protection is to avoid having to
disclose valuable information to the public (European Commission, 2013). If it is correct that one should
expect a greater knowledge diffusion effect from patents than from trade secrets, and governments want to
encourage such diffusion because it fosters innovation and growth, then it could be worth considering what
can be done to make filing for patents more appealing to firms when they have a choice between trade
secrets and patents. 67
Part of that consideration would necessarily involve the subject of cost, which is another factor that
motivates some firms – particularly innovative SMEs – to favour trade secrets protection over patent
protection (Brant and Lohse, 2013). It is clearly important for SMEs to have an affordable means of
protecting their valuable KBC. Granted, there may be a relatively higher societal cost with trade secrets in
that they probably generate less diffusion than there would be with a patent. However, that may be
preferable than not getting the innovation at all. Furthermore, when inventors opt for trade secrets
protection instead of a patent, they leave the door open for subsequent inventors to innovate in ways that
might have infringed the patent. Finally, making patents substantially cheaper might encourage a surge of
low quality, low value patent applications.
IP-Based Financing Deserves Attention
OECD data covering 2001 to 2011 indicate that, although young firms account for only 17 percent of
total employment, they contribute disproportionately to job creation – 45 percent of the total – across a
group of 15 OECD countries that were studied (OECD, 2013c, p. 198). 68 However, there was substantial
variation within the sample, a fact that highlights the importance of national policies and business
environments in encouraging the formation and development of new businesses. Among the most
important factors affecting the success of young firms is the ease of access to financing. Capital is often
relatively difficult for young firms to obtain because they do not have long histories of consistently
repaying loans and they tend to lack collateral – or at least what banks have traditionally viewed as
collateral. But some young firms have untapped resources in the form of IP, which – if it can be properly
valued and if markets for IP-based financing are functioning well – can be used to persuade lenders to
provide financing.
This is a timely issue because even though young firms are responsible for so much job creation, it
became even harder for them to obtain financing between 2007 and 2012 (OECD, 2013c, p. 200). Of
course, not all start-ups need or merit external capital, and not all of them have IP. But due to the financial
crisis, banks were unable or less willing to provide loans to young, innovative start-ups, and venture capital
firms became more risk-adverse. The financiers therefore focused on more mature businesses, leaving an
important source of job creation underfunded. If IP-based financing had been less constrained and more
developed, it could have made the difference between success and failure for young firms with promising
IP. Policy makers interested in job growth may benefit from taking a closer look at what is constraining IPbased financing and what can be done to unleash it. That is the purpose of Chapter 9 of this Report.
Chapter 9 notes that asymmetric information, moral hazard, and certain other features of innovation
have the combined effect of driving interest rates for financing innovation higher than for other types of
financing. Those factors also lead to inefficiently low funding for innovative firms, in part because the
factors make it harder to use KBC as collateral. Knowledge-intensive start-ups and young SMEs are
probably the most financially constrained, essentially because they lack tangible capital and track records.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
58 | SYNTHESIS
They are therefore the ones that would stand to benefit the most if IP-based financing were more widely
available.
IP can facilitate financing, especially for SMEs, in two ways. First, IP can serve as a signal of a firm’s
quality (both managerial and technological) and potential, helping to reduce information asymmetries
between internal managers and external investors. Second, IP can boost profitability because it confers
exclusive rights to use inventions or creations, which can lead to competitive advantages. If there is a wellfunctioning secondary market for IP, IP can also be sold off if the firm that owns it has trouble repaying its
loans. In other words, IP can serve as collateral in debt financing.
Chapter 9 further explains that debt financing connected to IP (i.e. mainstream and IP-backed lending
and securitisation, IP sales and lease backs, and venture debt) is growing, but the lack of data prevents
researchers from determining its actual size. In any event, large firms use debt financing more than smaller
firms in IP-intensive sectors, due to the complexity of these transactions and the fact that large firms more
often have IP that is already commercialised and earning a return. Smaller firms must rely more on equity
financing, in which angel investors or venture capitalists recognise and estimate the present value of IP
assets that have not necessarily begun to generate profits yet. A substantial body of empirical work has
found that young, high-growth firms with IP assets receive more funding than firms without IP.
Nevertheless, IP-based finance is significantly under-used, especially by SMEs that are most in need
of it (Brassell & King, 2013). One major reason for that stems from a lack of opportunities to sell IP in a
secondary market, which is due to both uncertain redeployability and immature IP markets (Brassell &
King, 2013; European Commission, 2014).
Policy makers are striving to support IP markets in several countries. Generally, their efforts fall into
two categories: i) supporting greater transparency of IP ownership and transfer information via disclosure
requirements or measures to foster greater clarity in patent claims; and ii) creating new IP market
infrastructures. Transparency and reliability in IP markets require greater attention because they are
currently undermined by insufficient information on IP ownership and transfers, as well as by uncertainty
over the legal protection and technological breadth of IP rights (Harhoff, 2009; Brassell & King, 2013;
Terroir, 2014). To promote transparency in ownership and transfers information, new disclosure
requirements could be introduced, for example through reporting regimes managed by IP offices. An
example of this type of measure is President Obama’s announcement of an executive action in June 2013
to increase transparency in the patent system by requiring patent owners and applicants to provide the
USPTO with up-to-date information on the attributable owner of patents and patent applications. 69
Examples of measures to create new IP market infrastructures are the UK’s Copyright Hub, an online
licensing and copyright education platform, and Denmark’s IP Marketplace, an online market where IP
owners and buyers can list, buy, sell, and license intellectual assets. 70
Another approach that governments can take is to help manage the risks associated with the
collateralising IP. Government agencies and development banks can do that through risk-sharing
mechanisms. Those mechanisms must allow IP to count as a credit-scoring enhancement. Alternatively,
governments could support the formation of IP insurance companies, though it remains unclear exactly
how best to do so.
Building awareness and trust within SMEs and the financial sector with regard to IP-based financing
is also crucial to facilitate the rise of IP as a full-fledged asset class. Awareness of the potential value of IP
for obtaining financing is a stubborn constraint. As we have seen, for most firms, registered forms of IP are
not the method of choice for protecting intellectual assets. Instead, they tend to rely on secrecy,
complexity, and/or first mover advantages. This is especially true of young, innovative firms (OECD,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
59 | SYNTHESIS
2011; Brassell & King, 2013). Policy makers can help by designing and implementing awareness
campaigns and by increasing the reliability of valuation standards and corporate reporting of IP assets.
Better Copyright Data Will Enable Data-Driven Copyright Policy
Part 3.1 showed that, where comparative data are available, investment in copyright has grown more
than investment in any other form of IP, that it is the largest component of IP-protected investment, and
that job growth in copyright-intensive industries has been much better than that in trademark and patentintensive industries. Nevertheless, patents have received far more scholarly attention than copyright
(WIPO, 2011, Chap. 2, p. 75). One reason for that discrepancy is that while patent-related data is plentiful,
given the requirement of filing a patent application, less information about copyright is publicly available.
Researchers go where the data are, and patent systems have plenty of data. To enable better-informed
policy making decisions, copyright has some catch up to do.
The relative lack of copyright information is mainly due to the fact that most copyrights are not
registered in most countries. There are some databases, thanks to public registration systems in some
countries as well as certain private sector organisations. But they do not provide comprehensive coverage
of all copyrighted works and they tend to be incompatible with one another (U.S. Dept. of Commerce,
2013, at 89-94). Consequently, it is harder to determine systematically even quite basic information about
copyrights, such as how many there are and who owns them. Ideally, policy decisions about all forms of
IP, including copyright, would be supported by reliable data and objective analysis, so more investment in
collecting and measuring copyright data is worth considering. 71
This issue was discussed at the Expert Workshop (see Chapter 8) and there was uncharacteristically
broad agreement among the panellists that the lack of copyright data is a significant problem that needs to
be addressed. As one speaker said, policy makers need to help generate the data, not just consume it.
What can be done? One possibility is to implement more measures designed to encourage voluntary
registration. The main purpose of copyright registration is to create an official record of the date, owner
and content of a work so that there is always a reliable basis on which to adjudicate legal claims
concerning the work. But an added benefit of registration is that it could help to alleviate the dearth of data
on copyright that is impeding quantitative analysis of its benefits and weaknesses.
Other possibilities include funding research and surveys to estimate the benefits of more registration,
and changing accounting rules that apply to creative industries to enable better data collection.
Effective Tax Rates on Investments in IP
Phase 2’s tax component, a stand-alone report entitled “Effective Tax Rates on Investments in
Different Types of Knowledge-based Capital”, provides a framework for modelling effective tax rates for
different types and for different business uses of KBC (OECD, 2014d). The types of KBC include, for
example, computerised information, innovative property including R&D, and economic competencies. The
different business uses of KBC are i) self-constructed for long term use; ii) self-constructed for sale; and
iii) acquired KBC. Part of the report addresses design features of KBC taxation, including deductibility of
expenses, taxation of future income at reduced rates (e.g. “patent boxes”), treatment of losses, and various
types of tax relief such as tax allowances and credits. Ultimately, the report shows differences in effective
tax rates across different types and uses of KBC. It then provides suggestions on how governments can
more cost-effectively direct their fiscal efforts to support the private sector in creating KBC.
The tax report notes, among other things, that tax incentives to encourage R&D must be carefully
designed to ensure they benefit all companies undertaking innovation investments, including SME’s and
start-up companies. It also observes that while KBC investments that fall into the category of R&D benefit
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
60 | SYNTHESIS
from tax subsidies in many countries, other types of KBC investment generally do not have specific tax
incentives. But non-R&D KBC may have potential positive spillovers, too, which would merit government
incentives.
Other Policy Challenges in Need of Further Study
Planned Work on Measuring Patent System Quality 72
The OECD’s Economics Department in collaboration with the Directorate for Science, Technology
and Innovation (DSTI) is designing a data collection exercise to facilitate the construction of new policy
indicators related to patent rights. This exercise is organised around two main pillars. First, a questionnaire
is being developed which aims to collect detailed information on countries’ rules, laws and standards, as
well as capacities, for reviewing patent applications, granting patents, litigating validity and infringement
cases, and determining outcomes in those cases.
Second, the Secretariat expects to produce a proposal by March 2015 for a project that will identify
the key features of patent systems that influence economic outcomes and summarise a new indicator.
The remainder of this section of this chapter suggests, in order of priority, a number of other policy
challenges that are not addressed, or that are only partly addressed, in the phase 2/IP report.
Leveraging the Patent Value Indicators to Gain Further Insights on Innovative Activity
As mentioned above, when statistics compiled from patent applications filed with the European Patent
Office were fed into the patent value indicator algorithms developed in Chapter 2, the results varied from
indicator to indicator. However, by looking at all of the indicators’ results, one could compile country
profiles from which a more comprehensive picture of each country’s innovative strengths and weaknesses,
to the extent that they are reflected in patenting activity, would emerge. One must bear in mind the earlier
discussion about the limits of the association between patenting and overall innovation, but nevertheless,
data from other patent offices and expanded time horizons could be fed into the indicators to enrich the
results. Furthermore, by linking the indicator data to data related to countries’ industrial structure and
framework conditions, it would also be possible to identify and analyse the factors and conditions that
foster (or hinder) the high-value patenting activity and hence the competitiveness of firms, industries, and
economies. Those additional projects have not been undertaken, but now that the indicators have been
created it would be possible to do them.
IP Bundles
In the past, firms that used IP tended to rely more frequently on one particular type, and to the extent
that they owned multiple kinds of IP, they may have been used in very distinct parts of the firm’s business
operations. For example, pharmaceutical companies relied primarily on patents (and still do), while soft
drink makers relied heavily on trade secrets. Media companies could rely almost exclusively on copyright
while maintaining trademarks on their brand names. Today, more companies use a bundle of IP rights to
protect their KBC. For instance, in-house software used in product design and manufacturing is common at
larger firms and is typically protected by copyright, while the products themselves may be protected by
patents, trademarks, and/or even more copyrights. Indeed, there is evidence suggesting that firms
worldwide increasingly rely on the joint use of patents, trademarks, and industrial designs (OECD, 2013c,
p. 186).
How are firms using bundles of different types of IP to be maximally competitive? How do the
different types of IP interact and complement each other? Are those interactions promoting or harming
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
61 | SYNTHESIS
innovation? Why do firms sometimes specifically choose not to use certain types of IP to protect their
KBC?
Sub-topics include:
•
Introduction to IP Portfolios – What do companies with multiple types of IP typically use the
different types for? In other words, why do they choose one form of IP protection over another for
a given invention, creation or idea? Is it more common in today’s economy than it was in the past
for firms to have substantial amounts of multiple types of IP? If so, what drove that change? How
do the different types of IP interact and complement each other? Are those interactions promoting
or harming innovation?
•
Strategic Use of IP Portfolios – Do companies sometimes use multiple types of IP in ways that
provide greater-than-optimal protection? If there are loopholes or faults in the frameworks, what
should be done to fix them? In what ways are the different types of IP and associated policies
working well together? How are those complementarities stimulating or inhibiting greater
innovation?
The Competition/IP Interface
There is no shortage of challenges for policy makers at the intersection of competition and IP regimes.
These include: how to make the FRAND concept clearer and more enforceable (FRAND means “fair,
reasonable, and non-discriminatory”; holders of standard-essential patents sometimes commit to FRAND
terms for licensing their patents before their technology is incorporated into the standard), hold-up and
reverse hold-up in standard-setting situations, reverse-payment settlements in the pharmaceutical industry,
and the behaviour of patent aggregators and how to monitor and analyse their acquisitions to protect
competition, given that markets for the relevant products might not even exist yet. There have also been
claims that patent assertion entities sometimes use their patents in a manner that violates competition laws
(Carrier, 2013; Guniganti & Knox, 2013; Wyatt, 2013).
Collaborative Innovation
New technologies have been emerging out of the cross-fertilisation of different fields, such as the
combination of biology and computer programming to form synthetic biology technologies. In addition,
open innovation and open access have increased the frequency of joint inventions and authorships. Not all
IP systems currently handle collaborative efforts to invent very well. When there are multiple contributors
to an invention and/or their contributions overlap, it is not necessarily obvious how to allocate IP rights in
all regimes, though it is in some. This is an issue for both patents and copyrights. How economically
significant is the problem? Is there a best approach? Can we identify regimes where the allocation of rights
are clearly delineated and encourage others to align with those best practices?
Patent Thickets
A patent thicket is a high density of patent rights issued in a certain technical area, which creates an
overlapping web of IP rights that must be navigated in order to commercialise a product. The potential
difficulties caused by a patent thicket could be amplified if there is low patent quality (meaning inaccurate
patent claims and patents that are not genuinely novel or non-obvious). Patent thickets are most frequently
mentioned as a concern in high tech and complex product industries, like ICT. A 2013 report
commissioned by the United Kingdom’s Intellectual Property Office, for example, found “overwhelming
evidence that patent thickets arise in specific technology areas” and its econometric analysis shows that the
density of patent thickets in given technology areas correlates with reduced entry into patenting in those
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
62 | SYNTHESIS
areas (Intellectual Property Office, 2013). The degree to which thickets retard innovation, however,
remains unclear, as high tech and ICT industries continue to innovate, develop, and grow rapidly.
Moreover, there can be over-lapping patent rights even in the case of a well-defined patent scope on
perfectly valid patents (Shapiro, 2001). Cross licensing arrangements and patent pools have been identified
as tools that can help with navigating patent thickets.
Conclusion
This chapter has provided an overview of the report, highlighting the key findings related to the main
themes: the importance of IP as a source of growth and innovation and the effects on IP systems and
stakeholders of several major developments, especially content digitisation and the growth of the Internet.
The overview shows that in spite of substantially changed technological and economic conditions, IP
remains vitally important to innovation, employment, and growth. Those changed conditions have,
however, created a number of challenges that stakeholders are working through. It is clear that having
more complete data on IP to serve as an underpinning for policy discussions would be extremely helpful.
However, so would deeper thinking about what IP’s fundamental purpose is because debates about optimal
frameworks also need to be grounded by clear principles and standards. Those are not always apparent in
IP discussions, particularly where copyright is concerned. Yet copyright appears to be the most
economically significant type of IP, it seems to be the form of IP that has been most affected by
digitisation and the Internet, and it generates the most controversy.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
63 | SYNTHESIS
ANNEX SUMMARY OF PHASE 1’S MAIN FINDINGS
At the start of 2011 the OECD began work on a two-year project entitled New Sources of Growth:
Knowledge-based Capital. The motivation for the project was two-fold. The first was to examine in depth
a finding highlighted by the OECD’s 2010 Innovation Strategy, namely that many firms that innovate do
not invest in R&D. Instead, innovation in such firms is based on investments in a wider range of intangible
assets – knowledge-based capital (KBC). Secondly, the NSG-KBC project aims to help governments and
policy analysts better understand the determinants of growth. Today, the importance of growth can barely
be overstated. The drawn-out nature of the global crisis, sluggish macro-economic conditions in many
OECD economies, weak labour markets and burgeoning public debt have all added urgency to the search
for new sources of growth. Furthermore, rapidly ageing populations, combined with natural resource
constraints, mean that the future of growth in advanced economies will increasingly depend on
productivity-raising innovation. Drawing on inputs from across the OECD Secretariat, the work
summarised in this synthesis report aims to provide evidence of the economic value of knowledge-based
capital as a new source of growth and to improve understanding of current and emerging policy challenges.
KBC results from business investment in non-physical assets such as research and development
(R&D), data, software, patents, new organisational processes, firm-specific skills and designs. In many
OECD countries, business investment in KBC has increased faster than investment in physical capital
(machinery, equipment, buildings). In some countries, business investment in KBC significantly exceeds
investment in physical capital.
KBC and growth
Inherent features of KBC are growth-promoting, and various forms of evidence link business
investment in KBC to growth and productivity change. Unlike physical capital, KBC can foster growth
because the initial cost incurred in developing certain types of knowledge is not re-incurred when that
knowledge is used again. This can lead to increasing returns to scale in production. Investments in many
forms of KBC – such as R&D, design and new business processes – also create knowledge that spills over
into other parts of the economy, again spurring growth. Growth accounting studies for the European Union
and the United States show that business investment in KBC contributes 20% to 27% of average labour
productivity growth. And during the global crisis, investment in KBC has been relatively resilient. KBC is
also transforming the determinants of competitive success for firms. For instance, in the automotive sector,
the cost of developing new vehicles is increasingly dominated by software, with high-end vehicles relying
on millions of lines of computer code.
As overall business investment in KBC increases – and because of KBC’s particular economic
features, especially its intangible nature – certain key policy settings need to be updated. Ensuring that
policies are up to date and conform to good practice is essential in the fields of taxation, innovation,
entrepreneurship, competition, corporate reporting and intellectual property. This also holds for policies
that enable the exploitation of data as an economic asset. The rising importance of KBC also amplifies the
importance of some framework policies already understood to be essential, such as education. Getting the
key framework conditions right, while a challenge, is in fact a low-cost step for policy makers in fiscal
terms.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
64 | SYNTHESIS
Innovation
The breadth of the assets that make up KBC points to the need for policy makers to adopt an enlarged
concept of innovation, beyond the conventional view in which R&D is pre-eminent. Other assets such as
organisational capital and design, and the ability to create value from data, are important arenas of
innovation and productivity growth that often require specific policy action. Well-designed support
measures – such as those that facilitate access to finance for innovative firms – along with frameworks that
foster collaboration to innovate, supply-side measures that support KBC investments in areas of highest
social return, and the redesign of some long-standing innovation programmes, are all important. And
demand-side policy – particularly innovation-oriented competitive public procurement – could help
support KBC investments that also meet public needs. Policy stability – keeping policy uncertainty to a
minimum – is also important.
Entrepreneurship and business development
The accumulation and optimal use of KBC requires experimentation (for instance with new business
models and organisational forms) in firms of all sizes. Evidence from thirteen OECD countries for 2001-11
shows that young firms (i.e. below five years of age), many of which use KBC intensively, accounted for
18% of total employment but generated 47% of all new jobs created. Policy should make it easier for firms
to develop and commercialise new ideas by lowering the costs of failure and encouraging firms to take
risks and experiment with potential growth opportunities. All this requires well-functioning product and
labour markets. Also essential are bankruptcy laws that do not overly penalise failure (reducing the
stringency of bankruptcy legislation from the highest to the average level in the OECD could raise capital
flows to patenting firms by around 35%) and well-functioning systems of debt and early-stage equity
finance. Indeed, the countries that invest more in KBC are those that reallocate resources to innovative
firms more effectively. As a share of gross domestic product (GDP), the United States and Sweden invest
about twice as much in KBC as Italy and Spain, and patenting firms in the United States and Sweden
attract four times as much capital as similar firms in Italy and Spain. Macroeconomic and political
uncertainties are also likely to hinder business investment in KBC.
Taxation
A wide variety of tax policies affect innovation and growth, as examined in previous OECD
publications such as Tax Policy Reform and Economic Growth (2010). Work reported here focuses on
effects on KBC investment by multinational enterprises (MNEs) of limited corporate income tax on returns
on investment. R&D tax incentives play a central role in many countries in encouraging investment in
KBC. However, the effective tax rate on such investments depends also on other aspects of the tax regime,
including not only explicit government policies (such as ‘patent boxes’) but also the cross-border tax
planning strategies now widely used by MNEs. New analysis is provided that finds that overall tax relief
for R&D by MNEs, when factoring in relief resulting from cross-border tax planning by MNEs, could well
be greater than governments foresaw when their R&D tax incentives were designed. The study considers
how MNEs are able to transfer KBC to offshore holding companies, and how interactions of tax systems
may encourage the use of KBC in foreign rather than domestic production. Consequently, countries may be
losing tax revenue from the commercialisation of subsidised R&D and foregoing some potential domestic
knowledge spillovers associated with production (while still gaining the benefits of knowledge spillovers
from the subsidised R&D performed locally). Furthermore, ‘stand-alone’ firms that are not part of a
multinational group of companies, and thus are unable to adopt cross-border tax-planning strategies, may
be placed at a competitive disadvantage, relative to MNEs, in undertaking and exploiting R&D. The
findings add to arguments for:
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
65 | SYNTHESIS
•
Targeting R&D tax credits on ‘stand-alone’ firms without cross-border tax planning
opportunities. This message is further supported by other OECD analysis showing that fiscal
incentives may favour less dynamic incumbents at the expense of dynamic young firms.
•
Reducing unintended tax relief for MNEs on the exploitation of KBC through international cooperation. New work to address base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS) should take into
account growth in the importance of KBC and intra-group trade in intangibles.
•
Recognition of the risk that the increasing reliance of countries on tax incentives for R&D
could, in some cases, increase foregone tax revenue without resulting in ‘incremental’ R&D
(i.e. additional R&D spurred by the incentive) and without increasing income from R&D
commercialisation. In this environment, it is essential to pay careful attention to the design of
R&D tax credits to reduce these risks.
•
Gathering more data to estimate the amounts of income being shifted to no-/
low-tax countries through MNE tax planning involving KBC, given potentially significant
implications of this planning for countries’ public finances.
Competition policy
Industries founded on KBC raise new issues for competition policy. This is particularly true for the
digital economy. Never before have leading firms grown so large so quickly, and the nature of competition
also differs in some respects from other sectors. Some experts have observed, for example, that unlike
traditional manufacturing sectors, the digital economy’s most meaningful competition takes place among
platforms created by companies that use very different business models, rather than among companies that
all follow more or less the same model. Apple, Google and Microsoft illustrate that point, as they all
compete in the market for mobile phone operating systems but each has a different business model.
Competition among platform providers may therefore be more important to innovation and consumer
welfare than competition within platforms (such as rivalry among companies that create apps for the
iPhone). Competition policy should: properly account for inter-platform competition; promote the
elimination of unnecessarily anti-competitive product market regulation; and include the effective
enforcement of competition law, which will protect and encourage innovation.
Intellectual property rights
High-quality intellectual property rights (IPR) are an increasingly important framework condition.
The rise of KBC is shifting IPRs from a largely technical area that is important to a few sectors to an area
with economy-wide prominence. Concerns are growing that not all facets of IPR are well suited to this
more pervasive role and that some intellectual property regimes have not kept pace with technological
change (many copyright systems were designed for a world of paper and print and may inhibit new digital
services). In a world increasingly based on knowledge assets:
•
IPR systems must be coupled with pro-competition policies and efficient judicial systems.
•
Steps should be taken to address the erosion of patent quality (i.e. the accuracy of patent claims
and whether patents reflect genuinely novel innovations). OECD data suggest that patent quality
across the OECD area has eroded steadily over the last decade.
•
There is a need for greater mutual recognition and compatibility across IPR systems
internationally (for instance to permit cross-border copyright licensing). Better understanding is
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
66 | SYNTHESIS
needed of how firms combine different IPRs (not only patents, but also trademarks, design
rights and copyrights) in their overall innovation strategies.
Capturing value in global value chains
The geographic fragmentation of production chains is a salient feature of the global economy.
Investment in KBC plays an important role in global value chains (GVCs) and international
competitiveness. The highest level of value creation in a GVC is often found in upstream activities such as
concept development, R&D or the manufacture of key parts and components and in certain downstream
activities such as marketing, branding or customer service. These activities all involve KBC and define the
extent to which firms generate the value available through GVCs. Getting policies and framework
conditions right is important to ensure that high-value jobs are created and maintained in GVCs. China,
Brazil and other emerging economies are also making concerted efforts to help their businesses develop
KBC.
Financial markets
In traditional debt markets, tangibles (assets such as equipment and structures) have well-defined
market prices and readily serve as collateral. While there are innovations in the securitisation of debt using
KBC, more could be done (for instance by facilitating robust markets for intellectual property). The
increasing importance of KBC underscores the need for market-enhancing policy instruments to address
shortfalls of early-stage risk capital that affect young KBC-intensive firms and the need for better ways for
firms to communicate the value of KBC in their business models.
Corporate reporting
The value of many of the world’s most successful companies resides almost entirely in their KBC. In
2011, for example, physical assets accounted for only about 13% of the value of Nestlé, the world’s largest
food company. Across countries, there is a positive correlation between the market value of firms and
investment in KBC. Nevertheless, corporate financial reports provide limited information on companies’
investments in KBC. This may hinder corporate finance and governance. Governments might: i) support
better corporate disclosure by establishing voluntary recommendations and guidelines or by backing privatesector reporting initiatives; ii) create mechanisms to facilitate companies’ reporting of investments in KBC;
iii) introduce frameworks for auditors; iv) engage in international co-ordination to improve international
comparability of data and information supplied by companies; and v) promote the establishment of asset
classifications that would increase consistency in data collection and reporting.
Measurement
A fuller understanding of innovation and growth, and the design of better policy, require governments
to do more to measure investments in KBC and to agree on common measurement guidelines. Current
international accounting standards, such as the System of National Accounts, capture a number of KBC
investments, such as software and R&D, but efforts to develop guidelines for robust and comparable
measurement should continue. This will require significant investment in the statistics needed to measure
reliably all the forms of KBC referred to in this report. In the short to medium term countries are
encouraged to develop additional measures via satellite accounts to maintain the international
comparability of GDP. This will help to improve understanding of growth and productivity. As an
indication of the potential impact of better measurement, accumulated investments in KBC (not measured in
GDP) amounted to around USD 4.1 trillion in the United States in 2007. In fact, around 40% of growth is
still an unexplained “residual”, and better measurement of KBC can help fill a part of this gap.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
67 | SYNTHESIS
Using data as an economic asset
Creating economic value from large data sets is at the leading edge of business innovation, while
companies that base key decisions on data analytics outperform other firms. While there is no clearly
optimal policy in this fast-evolving field, it is evident that to unlock major economic benefits all OECD
governments must do more to implement coherent policies in the fields of privacy protection, open data
access, information and communications technology (ICT) infrastructure and ICT-related skills.
Education and training
Growing business investment in KBC amplifies the importance of getting human capital policies
right. Human capital is the foundation of KBC: software, for example, is essentially an expression of
human expertise translated into code. The rapid evolution of different parts of the KBC-intensive economy
inevitably generates skills shortages. Research in the United States suggests a shortfall of some 1.5 million
managers and analysts with adequate understanding of the business benefits of data. The NSG-KBC
project highlights the importance of policies to balance skills supply and demand efficiently (as elaborated
in the OECD Skills Strategy). Public-private partnerships can also help to better align curricula and
programmes with the needs of business. And given highly constrained public finances, in countries where
educational attainment is already high, efforts to improve the quality of education will often be a priority.
The rise of KBC has profound implications for employment and earnings inequality. A KBC-based
economy rewards skills and those who perform non-routine manual and cognitive tasks, but may also
reward investors (who ultimately own much of the KBC) over workers (in the United States, for instance,
wages as a share of GDP are at an all-time low). Rising investment in KBC can create winner-takes-all
opportunities for a few, while entire occupational categories can be replaced by machines and software.
KBC changes the demand for skills, and to the extent that workforce skills can adjust rapidly to new
technologies, aggregate growth will be enhanced without greatly exacerbating income inequality. Major
societal challenges will certainly arise as driverless vehicles, machine-based X-ray diagnostics, automated
report-writing, and many similar advances in digital technology become widespread.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
68 | SYNTHESIS
NOTES
1
C. Corrado, C. Hulten and D. Sichel (2006), “Intangible Capital and Economic Growth,” Federal Reserve
Board
Discussion
Series
2006-24,
available
at:
www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2006/200624/200624pap.pdf; Leonard Nakamura (2008), “Intangible
Assets and National Income Accounting,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper No. 0823, available at: http://philadelphiafed.org/research-and-data/publications/working-papers/2008/wp0823.pdf; C. Corrado, C. Hulten and D. Sichel (2009), “Intangible Capital and U.S. Economic Growth”,
Review of Income and Wealth, Series 55, No.3, September, available at: www.conferenceboard.org/pdf_free/IntangibleCapital_USEconomy.pdf.
2
Note that non-exclusive frameworks like open source and public domain are also important for creativity
and innovation because they provide a common ground on which creativity and innovation – using private
or exclusive rights – can flourish. For example, the publication policies of firms like IBM show how
publication to prevent patenting can be used successfully to establish technology standards which
customers and others can use. Research commissioned by the UK’s Intellectual Property Office
(www.create.ac.uk/blog/2014/12/10/create-event-reflects-on-value-of-the-public-domain/) shows how the
use of public domain creative material raises the commercial attractiveness of investment in new creative
work. Non-exclusive frameworks complement, rather than compete with, IP rights.
3
See www.oecd.org/general/ministerialcouncilmeeting2012-chairssummary.htm;
www.oecd.org/mcm/chairssummary-oecdministerialcouncilmeetingmcm29-30may2013itsallaboutpeoplejobsequalityandtrust.htm; and www.oecd.org/mcm/mcm-2014-chair-summary.htm.
4
See www.oecd.org/mcm/C-MIN(2013)1-ENG.pdf; and www.oecd.org/about/secretary-general/MCM2014-Strategic-Orientations-SG.pdf.
5
In some countries, creative expression created by producers of sound recordings as well as performers are
protected under “related rights” or “neighbouring rights” regimes in national copyright laws, but they are
considered part of the copyright “community”.
6
Many countries do not define trade secrets expressly as IP, even though they are covered under the TRIPS
Agreement (Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, the first international
agreement to protect trade secrets expressly). Most countries protect trade secrets under a civil statute,
while a growing number also provide supplementary protection under criminal law. In common law
countries, the protection of trade secrets was founded on common law court decisions and precedent about
agreements between employers and workers or between business partners. See Chapter 3, Approaches to
the Protection of Trade Secrets.
7
This should not be interpreted as suggesting that the effects of ICT development on KBC, including IP, are
limited to ICT industries themselves. ICT development is facilitating KBC in many other areas of the
economy, as well, like banking, agriculture, and scientific research.
8
See, e.g. OECD (2013a), p. 50 (“Recent decades have seen a trend for countries to strengthen patenting
regimes in favour of patent holders.”); Chapter 4 of this Report (showing that trade secrets protection has
grown stronger in both OECD and non-OECD countries over the past 25 years); Chapter 5 of this Report
(see in particular country studies of Australia, Canada, Japan, and Korea); Sell (2003), at p. 63 (noting that
“Over time, the scope of subject matter eligible for copyright protection has broadened considerably” and
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
69 | SYNTHESIS
that, for example, “[u]nder TRIPS computer programs are protected as ‘literary works’” and that “[w]hile
some users of copyrighted information have protested this expansion of copyright, the recent trend has
been to protect more rather than less.”); International Trademark Association Factsheet, “Types of
Protection: Nontraditional Trademarks” (“Traditionally, a mark will consist of a word, logo, or a
combination of both... However, over time other elements besides words, logos or graphic designs have
served to identify the source of goods or services, thus serving the function of marks. These are called
nontraditional
marks.”),
available
at
www.inta.org/TrademarkBasics/FactSheets/Pages/NontraditionalTrademarksFactSheet.aspx;
see
also
Copyright Term Extension Act of 1998 (amending 17 U.S.C. §§ 108, 203(a)(2), 301(c), 302, 303,
304(c)(2) to extend copyright term in the United States from life of the author plus 50 years to life of the
author plus 70 years); Directive 2011/77/EU (extending the term of copyright protection for performers
and sound recordings to 70 years in the EU); WIPO Copyright Treaty and WIPO Performances and
Phonogram Treaty (also known as the WIPO “Internet Treaties,” these treaties entered into force in 2002
and “update and supplement the major existing WIPO treaties on copyright and related rights, primarily in
order
to
respond
to
developments
in
technology
and
in
the
marketplace”
(www.wipo.int/copyright/en/activities/internet_treaties.html) by adding anticircumvention protection,
protection against tampering with rights management information, a communication to the public/making
available right, and by harmonising performers’ rights – changes that the International Intellectual Property
Alliance
describes
as
requiring
signatories
to
“upgrade
their
copyright
laws”
(www.iipa.com/wipo_treaties.html)); Gilson & LaLonde (2005). Of course, not every development has
moved in the same direction. For example, the United States Supreme Court recently held that an abstract
idea does not become patent-eligible merely because someone implements it through a generic computer.
Alice Corp. v. CLS Bank International, 573 U.S. ___ (2014). Although the opinion does not mention the
word “software,” it is expected to restrict patent rights for software. See Graham (2014) (quoting Professor
Mark Lemley: “I expect that holding to invalidate the majority of all [U.S.] software patents in force
today.”), available at www.law.com/sites/articles/2014/06/19/cls-bank-ruling-a-big-deal-for-valleysoftware-patents/.
9
See CISAC (2014), at 57-58 (indices of creativity correlated with the strength of national IP system); but
see Hargreaves (2011), at 19, (“Economic evidence is clear that the likely deadweight loss to the economy
exceeds any additional incentivising effect which might result from the extension of copyright term beyond
its present levels.”).
10
Big data also raises concerns about potential effects on employment and about the need to improve skills in
the work force, as well as about trust (an umbrella term that includes privacy, cybersecurity, and consumer
protection), which are discussed in detail in Chapters 5 and 6 of the other main phase 2 report, Data-Driven
Innovation for Growth and Well-Being.
11
That there is a real possibility that IP policies in OECD countries do not always succeed in striking such a
balance is suggested by a number of recent legal reforms and government or government-sponsored studies
that address the balance. See, e.g., Canada’s Copyright Modernization Act 2012, which enacted
amendments whose rationale was both to strengthen the ability of copyright owners to control the uses of
their online works and to improve the copyright law’s ability to spur creation and innovation and to support
new business models in the digital age. As noted in Chapter 5 of this Report, discussants at public
consultations on copyright modernisation in Canada were asked what sorts of copyright reforms would best
foster innovation and creativity. See also Van Der Noll, et al. (2013) (an economic study on flexible
copyright commissioned by the Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs, Agriculture and Innovation);
European Commission (2014) (Expert Group’s report on text and data mining); Hargreaves (2011);
Chapters 7 and 8 of this Report.
12
Open access commonly refers to efforts to make the outputs of publicly funded research more widely
accessible in digital format to the scientific community, the business sector, and society in general. See
Chapter 7.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
70 | SYNTHESIS
13
Partitioning strategies involve subdividing one (sometimes major) innovation into pieces and seeking to
patent them as separate inventions. (Giarratana & Fosfuri, 2007).
14
Patent congestion is a term that essentially means an overload of patent applications that results in less
rigorous patent examinations. (Caillaud & Duchêne, 2011).
15
Specifically, CEO Elon Musk announced that Tesla “will not initiate patent lawsuits against anyone who,
in good faith, wants to use our technology.” Finley (2014) (noting that Tesla CEO Elon Musk’s “stance
underscores the sentiment–widely held in Silicon Valley–that today’s technology moves too fast for the
U.S. patent system”). Musk added that Tesla will continue to file for patents, but when they are granted,
Tesla will “put them into what is essentially an open source category”. Ibid.
16
Examples of digital copyright exchanges include the Copyright Hub in the United Kingdom and SIPX in
the United States.
17
Given the multitude of IP policy challenges that are in need of attention and that many, if not all, of them
are complex, they could not all be adequately addressed in one project. This report, therefore, is not an
attempt to do that. Instead, it is an effort to make progress in certain key areas. A list of challenges that are
not addressed here and that remain ripe for further study is presented near the end of this chapter.
18
Here “society” is intended to mean society in an economy-wide sense, not consumers alone, so the societal
benefits we focus on are factors like innovation, productivity, and GDP growth. Also, the exchange
concept is weaker with respect to copyright than patents, but there is still a give and take in the sense that
copyright protection eventually expires and certain exceptions apply to it, but copyright also provides a
stronger incentive to create and disseminate content.
19
The summary of the Workshop reflects the information exchanged among the parties at that event. The
views presented at the Workshop and reflected in the summary are the experts’ own and do not necessarily
represent the views of the OECD or any of its Member countries.
20
Pallante (2013) (also noting that “authors do not have effective protections, good faith businesses do not
have clear roadmaps, courts do not have sufficient direction, and consumers and other private citizens are
increasingly frustrated” and that “Congress should approach the issues comprehensively over the next few
years as part of a more general revision of the statute).
21
Robert Goodlatte, interviewed by Tamlin Basin in Patent, Trademark & Copyright Law Daily, “Copyright
Review Process Will Continue into 2015; Education and Circumvention Will Be Next Issues Examined”
(August 20, 2014), available at www.bna.com/copyright-review-process-n17179894026/; see also
http://judiciary.house.gov/news/2013/04242013_2.html (in which Chairman Goodlatte acknowledges that
“[t]here is little doubt that our copyright system faces new challenges today” due to digitisation and the
Internet).
22
Commissioner Oettinger (Oettinger, 2015) stated: “The other sector we have to look at is copyright. In a
digital era, copyright legislation need[s] to be adapted, which will not be easy. On the one hand, we have to
preserve and foster our European culture and therefore protect the intellectual property. On the other hand,
there is an internet community which has other interests. In our reform we therefore . . . need to find a
reasonable balance between the rights of the producer, creator and users.”
23
United States Department of Commerce Internet Policy Task Force (2013), p. iii. The report further
explains that “[i]t is time to assess whether the current balance of rights, exceptions and responsibilities –
crafted, for the most part, before the rapid advances in computing and networking of the past two decades –
is still working for creators, rights holders, service providers, and consumers. The Internet must continue to
support a legitimate market for copyrighted works as well as provide a platform for innovation and the
introduction of new and dynamic services that drive digital commerce.” Ibid.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
71 | SYNTHESIS
24
Copyright
Modernization
Act,
S.C.
2012,
lois.justice.gc.ca/eng/annualstatutes/2012_20/FullText.html.
25
As a result of the work on the other main pillar of phase 2, which is the report entitled “Data-Driven
Innovation – Unleashing Data for Growth and Well-Being”, we will propose to develop an OECD Council
Recommendation on open access to data in collaboration with CSTP and GOV that would merge other
open data-related OECD Council Recommendations, in particular the OECD (2008) Council
Recommendation on Enhanced Access and More Effective Use of Public Sector Information developed by
CDEP in 2008 and the OECD Principles and Guidelines for Access to Research Data from Public Funding
developed by the CSTP in 2005.
26
An “IP system”, as the term is used in this report, is the law and policy framework that governs IP rights.
“Effectiveness” refers to how well the IP system promotes technological and artistic creation and diffusion,
as well as innovation.
27
The 12 jurisdictions studied in Chapter 5 are Australia, Canada, Chile, Egypt, the European Union, Italy,
Japan, Korea, Poland, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
28
The copyright-intensive industries are defined separately for each of the 12 jurisdictions studied, using a
methodology developed by WIPO (2003). In some cases that methodology was subsequently refined and
the updated methodologies are discussed in Chapter 5, as well. The original WIPO study identified nine
core copyright-intensive industries: press and literature; music, theatrical productions, and operas; motion
pictures and videos; radio and television programming; photography; software and databases; visual and
graphic arts; advertising; and copyright collective management societies.
29
Using value added and employment data for copyright intensive industries to measure copyright’s
economic importance is a rough approximation. It is an overestimate because it gives copyright the credit
for all of the economic activity in these industries. On the other hand, it is an underestimate because it
assigns no value to the non-economic (cultural) contributions made by copyrighted works, nor does it
capture the innovation that copyright enables.
30
The analysed period varies from country to country, but only the timeframes for Egypt and Japan do not
include the 2008 financial crisis or the years that followed it.
31
A handful of industries, however, reported greater patent effectiveness concerning product innovations.
These included medical equipment, drugs, special purpose machinery, computers, and automobile parts.
Ibid at 10 and Tables 1.1 and 1.2.
32
The number of patents granted annually around the world tripled from about 400,000 in 1995 to almost 1.2
million in 2012 (WIPO, 2013, p. 48, Figure A.1.2.1).
33
See, e.g., (Eaton, et al., 2004) at 48 (concluding that almost two-thirds of the roughly six percent annual
growth in European patents between 1991 and 2000 was caused by a decline in EPO application fees);
(Bessen & Hunt, 2004) (contending that US manufacturing firms were adding software patents to their
portfolios not as a result of more innovation but simply because software had become patentable and the
firms were using them to intimidate potential entrants, make competitors pay royalties, and defend
themselves from infringement lawsuits); (Hall & Ziedonis, 2001) (finding that the doubling of patenting
rates over a decade in the semiconductor field reflected firms’ desire to bulk up their patent portfolios in
order to blunt innovation-blocking strategies by rivals that owned other technologies necessary for making
semiconductor chips).
34
See, e.g., Merges (1999); National Academy of Sciences (2004) at 41-49. Consider the comments of an
executive from Texas Instruments, as well: “TI has something like 8000 patents in the United States that
are active patents, and for us to know what’s in that portfolio, we think, is just a mind-boggling, budgetbusting exercise to try to figure that out with any degree of accuracy at all.” Testimony of Frederick
c.20,
available
at
http://laws-
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
72 | SYNTHESIS
Telecky, US FTC/DOJ Hearings on Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the
Knowledge-Based Economy (28 February 2002), available at www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/020228ftc.pdf
(quoted in Kahin (2004) at 211). If a company with the resources of Texas Instruments cannot afford to
determine what it has in its own patent portfolio, one can imagine how hard it could be for small potential
entrants to determine their risk of triggering a patent infringement lawsuit; but see Walsh, et al. (2003) at
285 (finding that threats of patent infringement are not deterring much biomedical research, if any at all).
35
Lemley (2008) (the quotation is from the abstract of the online version of the article, available at:
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=999961&download=yes).
36
Jaumotte & Pain (2005) at 49 (finding that an increase of one unit in their model’s IPR index was
associated with an increase of just over five percent in R&D spending but was also estimated to raise the
total number of patents by over 30 percent).
37
Please note that Chapter 2 refers to the technological and economic value of patented inventions as “patent
quality.” However, the term “patent quality” can also mean other things, such as the likelihood that a patent
will survive a validity challenge in court. That is a different concept. To avoid confusion, the Synthesis
chapter refers to “technological and economic value” instead of “quality”.
38
The data are based only on patents granted by EPO; they do not include patents granted by national patent
offices. The analysis therefore allows no performance comparison of various patent offices.
39
See Chapter 2, Measuring the Technological and Economic Value of Patents. The downward trend in
technical and economic value can be seen in the composite index charts between the years 1990 and 2004,
as well as in the charts that break the index down by technology fields and countries from 1994 to 2004.
Data beyond 2004, though shown in the composite index charts, is unreliable because it suffers from a
timeliness problem. That is due to the five-year citation window used to compile the data. In other words,
after 2004 there is a reduced number of observations, which prevents a reliable measure.
40
This definition uses four components: the number of forward citations (up to 5 years after publication);
patent family size; number of claims; and the patent generality index. Only granted patents are covered by
the index.
41
The
letter,
dated
26
September
2013,
http://graphics8.nytimes.com/packages/pdf/business/26trolls-letter.pdf.
42
See Kitch (1980) (arguing that the greater appropriability comes about due to a decrease in the risk of
theft); Friedman, et al. (1991) (attributing greater appropriability to lower costs of protection where trade
secret laws are clear and enforcement is effective).
43
The sample is expanded to 37 countries and a 25-year range (1985-2010).
44
Please note that, like virtually all indicators, the TSPI is not without certain limitations, which are
acknowledged in Chapters 3 and 4. The TSPI captures stringency of protection only for those elements that
are expressly described in Chapters 3 and 4. Although there is a positive association of those aspects with
key indicators of economic performance and it appears fairly robust, that does not mean that all of the
possible complexities of the relationship were captured or that conclusions can be extended to other aspects
not covered in this Report. Instead, the chapters present an indication that protection for the TSPI-covered
elements of trade secrets appears to be positively associated with the areas of economic performance
considered in the chapters (selected innovation and international economic indicators).
45
For example, in the United Kingdom, the legal protection afforded to Registered Designs lasts up to 25
years and applies to both two and three dimensional designs, whereas the protection granted to unregistered
Design Rights expires sooner and applies only to three dimensional designs.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
is
available
at:
73 | SYNTHESIS
46
Different jurisdictions use different terms for registered designs, such as registered community designs,
design models, design patents, and industrial designs. However, regardless of the terminology used, a
design must be new and distinctive to be protected under the applicable law.
47
Note that OHIM began to accept filings for design rights in 2002, so these figures show the early phases of
the OHIM protection regime. Some of the increase in applications and the stock of registered designs over
the time period shown may reflect the initial novelty and subsequent maturation of the OHIM regime rather
than an increase in design activity.
48
Incidentally, the same study found that copyright and trademark protection were used by more firms (26%
and 12%, respectively), while only 3% used patents.
49
See also Hertenstein, et al. (2005) (finding that “good industrial design is related to corporate financial
performance and stock market performance”).
50
Hargreaves (2011) at 73 (“we have not found either a figure for the prevalence and impact of piracy
worldwide or for the UK in which we can place our confidence”); U.S. Department of Commerce, 2013, at
39 (noting that “copyright infringement over the Internet has proven difficult to quantify”); see also OECD
(2008) and Stryszowski (2009).
51
IFPI’s “Global Statistics: Facts and Stats” web page, at www.ifpi.org/facts-and-stats.php (last visited 26
September 2014); see also IFPI (2014).
52
Ibid.
53
Such laws have been enacted in Germany and Spain, are pending in Israel, and have been proposed in
France.
54
Congreso de Los Deputados, Proyectos de Ley 121/000081 Art. 32.2 (21 de febrero de 2014), p. 8;
Chappell (2014).
55
Data as of April 2014. See New York Times, “How the Recession Reshaped the Economy, in 255 Charts,”
5 June 2014, available at www.nytimes.com/interactive/2014/06/05/upshot/how-the-recession-reshapedthe-economy-in-255-charts.html. Data come from the United States Bureau of Labor Statistics’ Current
Employment Statistics program.
56
Copyright virtually always applies to publications, but not necessarily to research data, because the latter
typically lack the element of originality that is essential for copyright protection. In the European Union,
Japan, and South Korea, however, sui generis database rights also exist and can apply to research data.
57
Those outputs include articles, monographs, raw data, metadata, digital representations of pictorial and
graphical materials and scholarly multimedia material (see Chapter 7 of this Report).
58
See Berlin Declaration on Open Access to Knowledge in the Sciences and Humanities (October 2003),
available at: http://oa.mpg.de/lang/en-uk/berlin-prozess/berliner-erklarung/.
59
See www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/microsites/ostp/ostp_public_access_memo_2013.pdf.
60
See https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
61
More information on product access and usage limitations can be found in the Committee on Consumer
Policy’s 2013 analytic report Protecting and Empowering Consumers in the Purchase of Digital Content
Products OECD (2013d).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
74 | SYNTHESIS
62
See Pallante (2013) at 5 (“[T]he public is very confused. Many of you have told me that your constituents
have no idea what to do with copyright, whether they are teachers, private citizens in their homes, higher
education
institutions”);
see
also
www.consumerfocus.org.uk/policy-research/digitalcommunications/copyright.
63
The Federal Trade Commission held a series of hearings in 2008-09 that addressed these and many other
issues related to the notice provided in patents. See Federal Trade Commission (2011) at p. 15 (“The ability
of third parties to foresee evolving claims depends on the extent to which the specification provides
effective notice of the range of claims that ultimately might issue. The disclosure requirements of [35
U.S.C.] Section 112 (written description and enablement) provide protection against undue broadening of
claims through additions and amendments. Panelists from the IT industry expressed concern about how
well these protections allow them to foresee claims that might issue. One reason is the perceived lax
enforcement of the Section 112 requirements for IT patents.”); ibid at 110 & n.230 (“One concern raised
repeatedly during the hearings was that claims frequently use terms with no apparent definition or
explanation in the specification. Clarity would be added, and notice improved, if applicants were pressed to
include definitions or contextual explanations of key terms. . . . [T]he PTO’s just-issued Supplementary
Examination Guidelines take a substantial step in this direction” (citing 76 Federal Register at 7,166, which
encourages applicants to use glossaries as a best practice in patent application preparation )); ibid at 128
(“The lack of a common, predictable terminology, already identified as a concern affecting patent clarity,
particularly in IT, also undermines effective patent searching. Panelists noted that variation in the terms
used to describe inventions can limit the effectiveness of electronic database searches and called for
‘taxonomical advances’ to better represent the ‘intellectual space’ to be searched.”); see also National
Academy of Sciences (2004) at p. 63 (“While alternative means of technological diffusion . . . are
exceedingly robust, some features of the legal system make a patent a less than ideal vehicle for
communicating technical information in a timely way despite the requirement that it be written to enable a
person of ordinary skill in the art to practice the invention. First, a patent is written by an attorney or a
patent agent to persuade an examiner to grant and a court to uphold a property right of the desired scope.
Beyond the minimum disclosure required by the patent statute, the applicant has no incentive to disclose
information that would be useful to a potential competitor...”).
64
Incidentally, such efforts also improve the patent examination process. By linking their databases, patent
offices can improve the prior art searches that take place during their examinations. More thorough
searches lead to higher quality patents (in the sense that the patents are more likely to withstand legal
challenges to their validity).
65
Not all patentable KBC could be protected as a trade secret, and not all KBC that could be protected by
trade secrets would be patentable. However, some KBC could be protected by either one. In referring to a
choice between patents and trade secrets here, we are referring only to situations where the nature of the
KBC makes such a choice possible. Sometimes the nature of the asset provides a clear indication that there
is only one type of appropriate protection. Patents generally offer protection for technological inventions
that are useful, novel and non-obvious. Trade secret protection is generally available for a broad range of
commercial information that is useful and not widely known, but it need not be novel. The broad scope
covers subject matter that may not be patentable such as know-how.
66
Arundel, 2001 (finding that European firms, especially smaller ones, tended to prefer trade secrets
protection to patent protection); Cohen, et al., 2000 (reaching similar conclusions based on a survey of US
firms).
67
Patents and trade secret laws provide different ways of protecting KBC. Not all patentable KBC could be
protected as a trade secret, and vice-versa. However, some KBC could be protected by either one (though
never both) and the inventor’s choice will affect the degree of knowledge diffusion that accrues to society.
68
These figures differ slightly from those reported in the Entrepreneurship and Business Development
section of the Annex to this chapter because the Annex refers to a different (slightly smaller) sample of
countries.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
75 | SYNTHESIS
69
See www.whitehouse.gov/the-press-office/2013/06/04/fact-sheet-white-house-task-force-high-tech-patentissues.
70
See www.copyrighthub.co.uk and www.ip-marketplace.org.
71
See National Research Council of the National Academies (2013) (describing a wide range of copyright
questions, calling for greater investment in data collection and suggesting approaches that would facilitate
it, with the objective of enabling better empirical research to inform decisions about the copyright system
in the digital age).
72
Please note that this work on patent system quality is quite different from the work in Chapter 2 of this
report, which is about the technological and economic value of individual patents and patent portfolios.
The term “patent system” here refers to the legal and policy regime that governs the way patents are
awarded, used, and enforced in a jurisdiction.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
76 | SYNTHESIS
REFERENCES
Almeling, D.S., D.W. Snyder, M. Sapoznikow, W.E. McCollum & J. Weader (2010), “A Statistical
Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in Federal Courts”, 45 Gonzaga Law Review 291
Anderlini, Jamil (2010), “Motorola Claims Espionage in Huawei Lawsuit,” Financial Times (July 22,
2010),
available
at:
www.ft.com/cms/s/0/616d2b34-953d-11df-b2e100144feab49a.html#axzz3GIbubD56
Arundel, Anthony (2001), “The Relative Effectiveness of Patents and Secrecy for Appropriation”,
30 Research Policy 611
Australian Law Reform Commission (2014), “Copyright and the Digital Economy,” available at
www.alrc.gov.au/publications/copyright-and-digital-economy-alrc-122-summary
Bessen, James & Robert Hunt (2004), “The Software Patent Experiment,” in OECD, Patents, Innovation
and Economic Performance, Conference Proceedings
Bessen, James & Michael Meurer (2014), “The Direct Costs from NPE Disputes,” 99 Cornell Law Review
__ (forthcoming 2014), available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2091210
Bond, Shannon (2014), “Double-Digit Decline for Music Downloads,” Financial Times (3 July 2014),
available at www.ft.com/cms/s/0/266ef4c8-02f7-11e4-81b1-00144feab7de.html#ixzz36URLLpzp
BOP Consulting (2011), “Design Rights, an International Comparison”, Design Economics (Chapter 4),
Report 2011/8, commissioned by the Intellectual Property Office, available at:
https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/310671/ipresearchdesignsreport4-201109.pdf
BPI (British Phonographic Industry) (2013), BPI Yearbook 2013
Brant, J. & S. Lohse (2013), “Enhancing Intellectual Property Management and Appropriation by
Innovative SMEs,” Innovation and Intellectual Property Series, Research Paper No. 1, International
Chamber of Commerce
Brassell, M. & K. King (2013), “Banking on IP? The role of intellectual property and intangible assets in
facilitating business finance”, Report 2013/34 commissioned by The Intellectual Property Office,
available
at:
www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/312008/ipresearchbankingip.pdf
Brin, Sergey & Lawrence Page (1998), “The Anatomy of a Large-Scale Hypertextual Web Search
Engine”, 30 Computer Networks and ISDN Systems 107
Caillaud, Bernard & Anne Duchêne (2011), “Patent Office in Innovation Policy: Nobody’s Perfect,” 29
International Journal of Industrial Organization 242
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
77 | SYNTHESIS
Carrier, Michael (2013), “Patent Assertion Entities: Six Actions the Antitrust Agencies Can Take,” CPI
Antitrust Chronicle (January 2013 (2))
Castro, Daniel (2010), “Better Enforcement of Online Copyright Would Help, Not Harm, Consumers,”
The Information Technology & Innovation Foundation (October 2010), available at:
www.itif.org/files/2010-copyright-coica.pdf
CEFIC (2012), Report on the Importance of Trade Secrets for Chemical Companies, The European
Chemical Industry Council
Chappell, Bill (2014), “Google News Is Taken Offline in Spain, After a Call for Payments,” NPR (16
December 2014), available at: www.npr.org/blogs/thetwo-way/2014/12/16/371253218/google-newsis-taken-offline-in-spain-after-a-call-forpayments?utm_source=npr_email_a_friend&utm_medium=email&utm_content=20141217&utm_ca
mpaign=storyshare&utm_term=
Charles River Associates (2014), Economic Analysis of the Territoriality of the Making Available Right in
the
EU,
study
commissioned
by
the
European
Commission,
available
at:
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/copyright/docs/studies/1403_study1_en.pdf
CISAC (2014), The Creative Industries and the BRICS,
www.cisac.org/CisacPortal/cisacDownloadFile.do?docId=26900
SG14-0749,
available
at:
Cohen, Wesley, Richard Nelson & John Walsh (2000), “Protecting Their Intellectual Assets:
Appropriability Condition and Why US Manufacturing Firms Patent (Or Not),” NBER Working
Paper No. 7552
Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia (2014), “La CNMC publica su Propuesta sobre la
modificación del Proyecto de Ley de la Propiedad Intelectual”, Note de Prensa (28 de mayo de
2014)
Cookson, Robert (2015), “Spotify Sees Holiday Surge in Subscription Numbers,” Financial Times (12
January
2015),
available
at:
www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/98ef9aa8-9a77-11e4-842600144feabdc0.html?o=os&siteedition=intl#axzz3Ohq0FdTk
Copyright Review Commission (Ireland) (2013), “Modernising
www.djei.ie/publications/science/2013/CRC-Report.pdf
Copyright”,
available
at
Davis, P., et al. (2008), “Open access publishing, article downloads, and citations: randomised controlled
trail,” BMJ (formerly the British Medical Journal); 337:a568, available at:
www.bmj.com/content/337/bmj.a568
Department for Culture, Media & Sport (UK) (2014), “Creative Industries Economic Estimates” (January
2014), available at: https://www.gov.uk/government/statistics/creative-industries-economicestimates-january-2014
Depreeuw, Sari & Jean-Benoît Hubin (2014), Study on the Making Available Right and Its Relationship
with the Reproduction Right in Cross-Border Digital Transmissions, report commissioned by the
European
Commission,
available
at:
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/copyright/docs/studies/141219-study_en.pdf
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
78 | SYNTHESIS
Design Council (2005), Design Index: The Impact of Design on Stock Market Performance, available at:
http://pinkfroginteractive.com/downloads/design_index_9199.pdf?Page/@id=6049&Session/@id=D
_5AFlTvf705tL9HUtNzYb&Document/@id=6923
Design Council (2009), Design in Britain 2008: National Survey of Firms 2008, available at:
www.designcouncil.org.uk/knowledge-resources/report/design-britain
Eaton, Jonathan, Samuel Kortum & Josh Lerner (2004), “International Patenting and the European Patent
Office: A Quantitative Assessment,” in OECD, Patents, Innovation and Economic Performance,
Conference Proceedings
Europe Economics (2011), Digital Content Services for Consumers: Assessment of Problems Experienced
by Consumers (Lot 1), Report 4: Final Report, http://ec.europa.eu/justice/consumermarketing/files/empirical_report_final_-_2011-06-15.pdf
European Commission (2007), Communication on Scientific Information in the Digital Age: Access,
Dissemination and Preservation, COM(2007)56, Brussels (14 February, 2007)
European Commission (2011), Special Eurobarometer 342, Consumer Empowerment, Conducted by TNS
Opinion & Social on request of Eurostat and DG SANCO, Survey co-ordinated by DG
Communication,
Brussels,
April
2011,
available
at:
http://ec.europa.eu/consumers/consumer_empowerment/docs/report_eurobarometer_342_en.pdf
European Commission (2012), “Commission Agrees Way Forward for Modernising Copyright in the
Digital Economy,” press release (5 December 2012), available at: http://europa.eu/rapid/pressrelease_MEMO-12-950_en.htm#PR_metaPressRelease_bottom
European Commission (2012a), “Towards Better Access to Scientific Information: Boosting the Benefits
of Public Investments in Research,” Communication to the European Parliament and the Council
COM(2012) 401 final (17 July 2012), available at: http://ec.europa.eu/research/sciencesociety/document_library/pdf_06/era-communication-towards-better-access-to-scientificinformation_en.pdf
European Commission (2013), Study on Trade Secrets and Confidential Business Information in the
Internal
Market,
prepared
by
Baker
and
McKenzie,
available
at:
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/iprenforcement/trade_secrets/index_en.htm#maincontentSec1
European Commission (2014), Final Report from the Expert Group on Intellectual Property Valuation,
available
at:
http://ec.europa.eu/research/innovationunion/pdf/Expert_Group_Report_on_Intellectual_Property_Valuation_IP_web_2.pdf
European Patent Office & OHIM (2013), “Intellectual Property Rights Intensive Industries: Contribution to
Economic Performance and Employment in the European Union”, available at
http://documents.epo.org/projects/babylon/eponet.nsf/0/8E1E34349D4546C3C1257BF300343D8B/
$File/ip_intensive_industries_en.pdf.
Federal Trade Commission (2011), The Evolving IP Marketplace: Aligning Patent Notice and Remedies
with Competition, available at: www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/reports/evolving-ipmarketplace-aligning-patent-notice-and-remedies-competition-report-federaltrade/110307patentreport.pdf
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
79 | SYNTHESIS
Finley, Klint (2014), “With Patent Giveaway, Tesla Shows Silicon Valley What Ingenuity Means,” Wired
(13 June 2014), available at www.wired.com/2014/06/tesla-patents/
Forbrukerrådet
(2007),
The
Arne
www.forbrukerradet.no/_attachment/1170139/binary/26930
Study,
available
at:
Fradsen, T. (2009), “The integration of open access journals in the scholarly communication system: Three
science fields”, 45 Information Processing and Management 131
Friedman, David, Richard Landes & Richard Posner (1991), “Some Economics of Trade Secret Law”, 5
Journal of Economic Perspectives 61
Fromer, Jeanne (2009), “Patent Disclosure,” 94 Iowa Law Review 539
Giarratana, Marco & Andrea Fosfuri (2007), “Product Strategies and Survival in Schumpeterian
Environments: Evidence from the US Security Software Industry,” 28 Organization Studies 909
Geiger, Christophe, et al. (2014), “The Three-Step-Test Revisited: How to Use the Test’s Flexibility in
National Copyright Law”, 29 American University International Law Review 581
Geist, Michael (2013), “Fairness Found: How Canada Quietly Shifted from Fair Dealing to Fair Use” in M.
Geist (ed.), The Copyright Pentalogy
Gilson, Jerome & Anne Gilson LaLonde (2005), “Cinnamon Buns, Marching Ducks, and Cherry-Scented
Racecar Exhaust: Protecting Non-Traditional Trademarks”, 95 Trademark Reporter 1
Goodridge, Peter, Jonathan Haskel & Gavin Wallis (2014), Estimating UK investment in intangible assets
and Intellectual Property Rights, Report 2014/36 commissioned by the Intellectual Property Office,
available at www.ipo.gov.uk/ipresearch-intangible.pdf
Graham, Scott (2014), “CLS Bank Ruling a Big Deal for Valley Software Patents,” Law.com (19 June
2014), available at www.law.com/sites/articles/2014/06/19/cls-bank-ruling-a-big-deal-for-valleysoftware-patents/
Gracz, Katarzyna & Primaveri di Filippi (2014), “Regulatory Failure of Copyright Law through the Lenses
of Autopoietic Systems Theory,” International Journal of Law and Information Technology, first
published
online
June
11,
2014,
available
at
http://ijlit.oxfordjournals.org/content/early/2014/06/11/ijlit.eau005.full?keytype=ref&ijkey=EzUAny
sUcC5f9xz
Grimmelmann, James (2010), “Some Skepticism about Search Neutrality,” in The Next Digital Decade,
Essays on the Future of the Internet (Berin Szoka & Adam Marcus, eds.)
Guibault, L. (2011), “Owning the Right to Open Up Access to Scientific Publications”, in L. Guibault & C.
Angelopoulos (eds.), Open Content Licences : From Theory to Practice
Guniganti, Pallavi & Ron Knox (2013), “Antitrust Study Still Needed after White House Action on Trolls,
Observers Say,” Global Competition Review (6 June 2013), available with subscription at
http://globalcompetitionreview.com/news/article/33612/antitrust-study-needed-white-house-actiontrolls-observers-say/
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
80 | SYNTHESIS
Hall, Bronwyn & Rosemarie Ziedonis (2001), “The Determinants of Patenting in the U. S. Semiconductor
Industry, 1980-1994,” 32 Rand Journal of Economics 101
Hall, Bronwyn, et al. (2012), The Choice between Formal and Informal Intellectual Property: A Literature
Review, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 17983
Hargreaves, Ian (2011), “Digital Opportunity: An Independent Review of Intellectual Property and
Growth”, available at www.ipo.gov.uk/ipreview-finalreport.pdf
Hargreaves, Ian & Bernt Hugenholtz (2013), “Copyright Reform for Growth and Jobs,” Lisbon Council
policy brief 13/2013, available at: www.lisboncouncil.net/publication/publication/95-copyrightreform-for-growth-and-jobs-modernising-the-european-copyright-framework.html
Harhoff, Dietmar (2009), “The Role of Patents and Licenses in Securing External Finance for Innovation,”
14 EIB Papers 74
Helft, Miguel (2014), “A Peek at Google’s M&A Ambitions,” Fortune (12 February 2014), available at:
http://fortune.com/2014/02/12/a-peek-at-googles-ma-ambitions/
Hertenstein, Julie, et al. (2005), “The Impact of Industrial Design Effectiveness on Corporate Financial
Performance”, 22 Journal of Product Innovation Management 3
IFPI (International Federation of the Phonographic Industry) (2014), Recording Industry in Numbers
Intellectual Property Office (2013), “A Study of Patent Thickets,” 2013/26, available at:
www.ipo.gov.uk/ipresearch-thickets.pdf
Intellectual Property Office (2013a), “Banking on IP”, available at www.ipo.gov.uk/ipresearch-bankingipsum.pdf
Intellectual Property Office (2014), press release, “Changes to Copyright Exceptions” (30 July 2014),
available at https://www.gov.uk/government/news/changes-to-copyright-exceptions
Intellectual Property Office and Viscount Younger of Leckie (2014), press release, “New Exceptions to
Copyright
Reflect
Digital
Age”
(1
June
2014),
available
at
https://www.gov.uk/government/news/new-exceptions-to-copyright-reflect-digital-age
Jankowski, John (2012), “Business Use of Intellectual Property Protection Documented in NSF Survey”,
National Center for Science and Engineering, Statistics Infobrief 12-307, National Science
Foundation, available at www.nsf.gov/statistics/infbrief/nsf12307/nsf12307.pdf
Jaumotte, Florence & Nigel Pain (2005), “From Ideas to Development: The Determinants of R&D and
Patenting,” OECD, ECO/WKP(2005)44, Economics Department Working Paper no. 457
Kahin, Brian (2004), “Through the Lens of Intangibles: What Patents on Software and Services Reveal
about the System,” in OECD, Patents, Innovation and Economic Performance, Conference
Proceedings
Kitch, Edmund (1980), “The Law and Economics of Rights in Valuable Information”, 9 Journal of Legal
Studies 683
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
81 | SYNTHESIS
Lansingh, V. & M. Carter (2009), “Does Open Access in Ophthalmology Affect How Articles are
Subsequently Cited in Research?”, 116 Ophthalmology 1425
Lawson, Bryan (2006), How Designers Think: The Design Process Demystified, 4th ed.
Lemley, Mark (2008), “Ignoring Patents”, 2008 Michigan State Law Review 19
Lemley, Mark (2011), “The Surprising Virtues of Treating Trade Secrets as IP Rights,” in R.C. Dreyfuss &
K.J. Strandburg (eds.), The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of Contemporary
Research
Levin, Richard, Alan Klevorick, Richard Nelson & Sidney Winter (1987), “Appropriating the Returns
from Industrial Research and Development,” 3 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 783
Maskus, Keith (2000), Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Economy, Institute for International
Economics
McGeer, Rick (2014), “A Transparent Google Search Benefits No One,” Financial Times (18 September
2014),
available
at:
www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/b827f988-3f41-11e4-a86100144feabdc0.html?o=os&siteedition=intl#axzz3E2KdE2Kf
Merges, Robert (1999), “As Many as Six Impossible Patents before Breakfast: Property Rights for
Business Concepts and Patent System Reform,” 14 Berkeley High Technology Law Journal 577
Motohashi, Kazuyuki, “Japan’s Patent System and Business Innovation: Reassessing Pro-Patent Policies,”
in OECD, Patents, Innovation and Economic Performance, Conference Proceedings (2004)
National Academy of Sciences (2004), A Patent System for the 21st Century (Stephen Merrill, ed.)
National Research Council of the National Academies, Copyright in the Digital Era: Building Evidence for
Policy (2013), available at: http://sites.nationalacademies.org/PGA/step/copyrightpolicy/
Office of the White House Press Secretary (2014), press release, “Executive Actions: Answering the
President’s Call to Strengthen Our Patent System and Foster Innovation (February 20, 2014),
www.whitehouse.gov/the-press-office/2014/02/20/fact-sheet-executive-actions-answering-presidents-call-strengthen-our-p
OECD
(2005),
“Digital
Music:
Opportunities
www.oecd.org/sti/ieconomy/34995041.pdf
and
Challenges”,
available
at:
OECD (2007), Principles and Guidelines for Access to Research Data from Public Funding
OECD (2008), The Economic Impact of Counterfeiting and Piracy, OECD Publishing, Paris. DOI:
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264045521-en
OECD (2011), Intellectual Assets and Innovation: The SME Dimension, OECD Studies on SMEs and
Entrepreneurship, available at: DOI: 10.1787/9789264118263-en
OECD (2011a), OECD Council Recommendation on Principles for Internet Policy Making
OECD (2013a), New Sources of Growth: Knowledge-Based Capital [Phase 1], Synthesis Report, available
at www.oecd.org/sti/inno/knowledge-based-capital-synthesis.pdf
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
82 | SYNTHESIS
OECD (2013b), “Knowledge Networks and Markets”, OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy
Papers, No. 7, OECD Publishing, available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k44wzw9q5zv-en
OECD (2013c), OECD Science, Technology, and Industry Scoreboard 2013, available at:
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/sti_scoreboard-2013-en
OECD (2013d), “Protecting and Empowering Consumers in the Purchase of Digital Content Products”,
OECD Digital Economy Papers, No. 219, available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k49czlc7wd3-en
OECD (2013e), “Background Paper for the TIP Workshop on Open Science and Open Data,”
DSTI/STP/TIP(2013)13
OECD (2014), Working Party on Innovation and Technology Policy Interim Report Draft of the OECD
Open Science Project, DSTI-STP-TIP(2014)9-ENG
OECD (2014a), Isabell Koske, Rosamaria Bitetti, Isabelle Wanner & Ewan Sutherland, “The Internet
Economy: Regulatory Challenges and Practices,” OECD Economics Department Working Paper No.
1171/2014
OECD (2014b), Dan Andrews, Chiara Criscuolo, & Carlo Menon, “Do Resources Flow to Patenting
Firms? Cross-Country Evidence from Firm Level Data,” Economics Department Working Paper No.
1127 (June 2014), available at: www.oecd.org/eco/workingpapers
OECD (2014c), Making Open Science a Reality (forthcoming report of the Working Party on Innovation
and Technology Policy)
OECD (2014d), Taxation of Knowledge-based Capital: Non-R&D Investments, Average Effective Tax
Rates, Internal vs. External KBC Development and Tax Limitations, Working Party No. 2 on Tax
Policy Analysis and Tax Statistics, Committee on Fiscal Affairs, OECD/CFA/WP2(2014)26
OECD (2014e), “Consumer Policy Guidance on Intangible Digital Content Products”, OECD Digital
Economy Papers, No. 241, OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jxvbrjq3gg6-en
Oettinger, Günther (2015), EU Commissioner for Digital Economy and Society, speech at the
Digital4Europe
Stakeholder
Meeting
(26
February
2015),
available
at:
http://ec.europa.eu/commission/2014-2019/oettinger/announcements_en
Ouellette, Lisa Larrimore (2012), “Do Patents Disclose Useful Information?”, 25 Harvard Journal of Law
and Technology 531
OpCit Project (2012), The Open Citation (OPCIT) Project, available at: http://opcit.eprints.org/
Page, Lawrence, Sergey Brin, Rajeev Motwani, & Terry Winograd, (1999) “The PageRank Citation
Ranking: Bringing Order to the Web”, Technical Report, Stanford InfoLab, available at
http://ilpubs.stanford.edu:8090/422/
Pallante, Maria (2013), “The Register’s Call for Updates to US Copyright Law,” Statement to the
Subcommittee on Courts, Intellectual Property and the Internet, Committee on the Judiciary, United
States
House
of
Representatives
(20
March
2013),
available
at
http://judiciary.house.gov/_files/hearings/printers/113th/113-20_80067.PDF
Park, Walter (2008), “International Patent Protection: 1960-2005”, 37 Research Policy 761
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
83 | SYNTHESIS
Pasquale, Frank (2010), “Trusting (and Verifying) Online Intermediaries’ Policing,” in The Next Digital
Decade, Essays on the Future of the Internet (Berin Szoka & Adam Marcus, eds.)
PricewaterhouseCoopers
(2014),
2014
Patent
Litigation
Study,
available
www.pwc.com/en_US/us/forensic-services/publications/assets/2014-patent-litigation-study.pdf
at
Primo Braga, C. (1990), “Guidance from Economic Theory”, in Strengthening Protection of Intellectual
Property in Developing Countries: A Survey of the Literature, Wolfgang Siebeck (ed.), World Bank
Discussion Paper No. 112, pp. 17-32
Sell, Susan (2003), Private Power, Public Law: The Globalization of Intellectual Property Rights
Shapiro, Carl (2001), “Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard Setting,”
in Adam Jaffe, Josh Lerner & Scott Stern (eds.), 1 Innovation Policy and the Economy 119-150,
available at www.nber.org/chapters/c10778.pdf
Stryszowski, P. and D. Scorpecci (2009), Piracy of Digital Content, OECD Publishing, Paris.
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264065437-en
Terroir, P. (2014), “Rebalancing the Patent Economy,” Intellectual Asset Management (March/April 2014)
p. 71
Triaille, J. (ed.) (2013), Study on the Application of Directive 2001/29/EC on Copyright and Related
Rights in the Information Society, De Wolf & Partners
Trotman, Andrew, “Apple Now Bigger than Russia’s Stock Market,” The Telegraph (14 November 2014),
available at: www.telegraph.co.uk/technology/apple/11232749/Apple-now-bigger-than-Russiasstock-market.html
UNESCO, 2012, Policy Guidelines for the Development and Promotion of Open Access, available at:
www.unesco.org/new/en/communication-and-information/resources/publications-andcommunication-materials/publications/full-list/policy-guidelines-for-the-development-andpromotion-of-open-access/
United States Department of Commerce (Economics and Statistics Administration & United States Patent
and Trademark Office) (2012), “Intellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: Industries in Focus,”
available at: www.uspto.gov/news/publications/IP_Report_March_2012.pdf
United States Department of Commerce Internet Policy Task Force (2013), Copyright Policy, Creativity,
and
Innovation
in
the
Digital
Economy,
(available
at:
www.uspto.gov/news/publications/copyrightgreenpaper.pdf
United States Government Accounting Office (2013), “Intellectual Property: Assessing Factors that Affect
Patent Infringement Litigation Could Help Improve Patent Quality,” August 2013, available at:
www.gao.gov/assets/660/657103.pdf
Swan, Alma (2010), “The open access citation advantage: studies and results to date”, e-print, available at:
http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/268516/
van der Noll, Rob, et al. (2012), Flexible Copyright: The Law and Economics of Introducing an Open
Norm in the Netherlands, available at: www.ivir.nl/publications/vangompel/Flexible_Copyright.pdf
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
84 | SYNTHESIS
Vasagar, Jeevan & James Fontanella-Khan (2014), “Berlin Pushes Google to Reveal Search Engine
Formula,” Financial Times (15 September 2014), available at: www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/9615661c3ce1-11e4-9733-00144feabdc0.html?siteedition=intl#axzz3E2KdE2Kf
Verdier, Thierry (2013), “Smart Trade: The Cross-Border Flow of Intellectual Property Comes under 21st
Century Economic Scrutiny,” 50 Finance & Development (December 2013), available at:
www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2013/12/verdier.htm
Wagner, A. Ben (2010), “Open Access Citation Advantage: An Annotated Bibliography”, Issues in
Science and Technology Librarianship volume 6, available at: www.istl.org/10-winter/index.html
Walsh, John, et al. (2003), “Effects of Research Tool Patents and Licensing on Biomedical Innovation”, in
Patents in the Knowledge-based Economy (Wesley Cohen & Stephen Merrill, eds.)
Walsh, Vivien (1996), “Design, Innovation and the Boundaries of the Firm”, 25 Research Policy 509
Westmore, Ben (2013), “R&D, Patenting and Growth: The Role of Public Policy,” OECD Economics
Department Working Papers, No. 1047, available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k46h2rfb4f3-en
WIPO (2003), Guide on Surveying the Economic Contribution of the Copyright-Based Industries, WIPO
Publication
No.
893(E),
available
at:
www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/copyright/en/performance/pdf/econ_contribution_cr_us.pdf
WIPO (2011), World Intellectual Property Report: The Changing Face of Innovation, available at
www.wipo.int/econ_stat/en/economics/wipr/wipr_2011.html
WIPO
(2013),
World
Intellectual
Property
Indicators
2013,
available
www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/freepublications/en/intproperty/941/wipo_pub_941_2013.pdf
at
Wyatt, Edward (2013), “U.S. Steps Up Scrutiny of Patents as Legal Disputes Increase,” International New
York Times (18 July 2013)
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
85 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
CHAPTER 2. MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
This chapter proposes a set of indicators that assess the economic and technological value of patented
inventions, as well as the impact they might have on subsequent technological developments. The
proposed measures can facilitate analysis both at the level of individual patents and at the aggregate
patent portfolio level. The chapter thus lays a foundation for potential work on policy-relevant
challenges such as quantifying patents’ contributions to innovation and growth; identifying the types of
firms that bring high value patents to the market; improving financing for innovative firms; comparing
firms’ innovation strategies and performance; and measuring the output of R&D activities and the
returns to R&D investments.
So far, the indicators have been “test-driven” with statistics compiled from patent applications that
were filed with the European Patent Office during the period 1990-2009. Each indicator suggests that
some countries have relatively strong innovative abilities and that some have relatively average or
weak abilities. Several experimental composite indices, based on groups of relevant factors, generated
consistent results. They all suggest that a) the average technological and economic value of inventions
protected by patents has eroded over time; b) patented micro and nano technologies have the highest
value; and c) Australia, Canada, Norway, South Africa, and the United Kingdom tend to generate
patents with the highest average value.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities or third
party. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and
Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
It should be noted that statistical data on Israeli patents and trademarks are supplied by the patent and trademark
offices of the relevant countries.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
86 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
ABSTRACT
This work contributes to the definition and measurement of the technological and economic value of
patents. It proposes a wide array of indicators capturing the technological and economic value of patented
inventions and the possible impact that these might have on subsequent technological developments. The
measures proposed build extensively upon recent literature, rely on information contained in the patent
documents, and are calculated on patent cohorts defined by the combination of the technology field and the
year of filing of patents. This is done to account for possible time- and technology-related shocks. The
description of the indicators is accompanied by statistics compiled on patents from the European Patent
Office, as well as tests aimed at addressing the sensitivity of the measures to alternative specifications and
the correlations that may exist among them. The indicators proposed, which can be constructed on all
patents, have the advantage of relying on a homogeneous set of information and of being comparable
across countries and over time. To facilitate their compilation on data from other Intellectual Property (IP)
offices, the SQL-based program codes used to calculate the indicators are also supplied. The paper is
further accompanied by a dataset – to be obtained upon request – containing the indicators calculated on
EPO patent documents published during the period 1978-2012, as well as some cohort specific statistics
(i.e. main moments and key percentiles).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
87 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
This work contributes to the definition and measurement of the technological and economic value of
patents. It proposes a number of indicators and an experimental composite indicator aimed at capturing the
technological and economic value of patented inventions, and the possible impact that these might have on
subsequent technological developments. The measures proposed build extensively upon recent literature
and rely on information contained in the patent documents.
The description of each indicator is accompanied by statistics compiled on patents from the European
Patent Office (EPO), as well as tests aimed at showing the sensitivity of the measures to alternative
specifications and the correlations that may exist among different indicators. The measures proposed,
which can be constructed on any patent, have the advantage of relying on a homogeneous set of
information and of being comparable across countries and over time.
The proposed measures aim to facilitate analysis both at the level of the individual patent and at the
aggregate patent portfolio level. They are intended to help address policy-relevant questions related to
topics such as: firms’ innovation strategies and performance; enterprise dynamics, including the drivers of
enterprise creation and of mergers and acquisitions; the determinants of productivity; financing innovative
enterprises; the output of R&D activities and the returns to R&D investments; R&D depreciation; and the
output of universities and public research organisations.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
88 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Introduction
It has been long argued that the “quality” of patented inventions varies widely from patent to patent
and that the likelihood to patent inventions of a given quality varies at both firm and industry levels
(Scherer, 1965). Simple as it may seem, the concept of patent quality has over time acquired a wide array
of meanings. The many definitions that exist are not exclusive, nor do they perfectly overlap, and users
tend to bridge them into somewhat intuitive notions of quality. For patent attorneys and engineers a high
quality patent can be a well written patent, whose content is clearly described, or a patent protecting a
major invention rather than an incremental step or technology. Legal scholars conversely tend to interpret
quality as the ability of a patent to withstand a legal challenge without being invalidated. For economists a
good patent is generally one that fulfils the key objectives of the patent system, i.e. to reward and
incentivise innovation while enabling diffusion and further technological developments (see Guellec and
van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, 2007, for a discussion).
Recently, there has been much discussion about patent quality, its meaning and definitions, as well as
how to measure it in practice and what it entails for innovation, entrepreneurship and technology
development 73.Whatever the definition of patent quality proposed, most stakeholders seem to agree about
the necessity to “raise the bar”, i.e. to raise the overall quality level of patents granted worldwide. Low
patent quality is widely perceived to generate uncertainty, to lower incentives to innovate, to stifle
technology development and to trigger a number of market failures that ultimately harm innovation,
entrepreneurship, employment and growth, as well as consumers’ welfare (see Hall et al., 2003, for a
discussion). For instance, it is well known that patents increase the likelihood of obtaining venture capital
and securing liquidity (Hall and Harhoff, 2012). However venture capitalists would not finance firms
against which patent infringement cases have been raised by another company or by a non-practising entity
(NPE) 74. As the likelihood of getting challenged in court is related to factors like the extent to which patent
claims are narrowly or broadly defined and the technological details of the patented invention, i.e. to patent
quality-related features, increasing the quality of these intellectual property rights (IPR) would help
mitigate market failures triggered by low patent quality.
This chapter starts from the premise that patent quality means the technological and economic value
of patented inventions (hereinafter, “patent value”). It contributes to the measurement of patent value and
the possible impact it might have on subsequent innovations. The chapter proposes a wide array of
indicators which mirror different – albeit often interrelated – aspects of patent value, sometime having a
mainly technological (e.g. backward citations) or preponderantly economic connotation (e.g. patent
renewals), or both (e.g. forward citations, generality). Also, depending on the indicator considered, the
meaning of patent value might be closer to that of private value or of social value. Addressing these
conceptual issues in more detail would go beyond the scope of this paper and its main empirical focus.
Interested readers are invited to refer to citations in the paper and to the OECD Patent Statistics Manual
(2009) for more information on the indicators and their possible interpretation.
The indicators proposed use pieces of information contained in the patent documents and are
compiled in such a way as to take into account the possible shocks that can occur over time in different
technology fields - for example, the sudden rise in patent application in some areas. The measures
proposed rely extensively upon recent literature and on earlier work carried out by the OECD Working
Party on Industry Analysis. All the indicators detailed in the present document can be constructed for all
patents applied under any jurisdiction, and have the advantage of relying on a homogeneous set of
information. This makes them generally comparable across countries and over time, and therefore suitable
for cross-country analysis.
The patent-based indicators herein should nevertheless be considered as proxies, since they do not
contain information about market transactions or the real use of the (patented) technologies. Moreover,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
89 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
almost all the measures detailed in the present work are retrospective in nature, and can only be compiled
ex-post, i.e. once the pieces of information they rely upon are included in the patent file. Also, the length of
period of observation for certain indicators inevitably depends on the underlying patent information from
which they are constructed. For instance, indicators based on backward citations, i.e. the citations to prior
art made in a patent, require a much shorter window of observation, and are thus more timely, than
measures based on forward citations i.e. the citations a patent receives from subsequent patents, which are
subject to ‘truncation’ effects.
The figures and statistics shown in the present document have been compiled using EPO patent
applications data contained in the April 2012 version of the EPO Worldwide Patent Statistical Database
(PATSTAT) and are presented according to the year in which the patent was filed, and according to the
country of residence of the applicants. The choice to focus on patent applications filed at one patent office
only is motivated by the awareness that intellectual property offices have to comply with country-specific
legislations and with a wide array of administrative regulations. These may ultimately lead to officespecific practices and to differences in terms of e.g. patent classes assigned to applications, propensity to
cite prior art, and number and length of claims contained in a patent document. Considering data from
several offices at a time would thus inevitably lead to biased indicators, as (at least) part of the figures
would be due to differences in office practices and regulations, rather than to the value of the patents
considered. Patent value indicators relying on data belonging to intellectual property offices other than the
EPO can nevertheless be easily calculated, as the piece of information on which the indicators rely are
contained in all patent files applied worldwide. Future research will investigate the differences that may
arise from the use of diverse data sources, and its main determinants.
In this paper, statistics are generally presented in the form of normalised indexes ranging between
zero and one. These are obtained by dividing the initial results by the maximum score obtained by any
patent in the same year and technology field cohort. Moreover, and in order to reduce the potential
distortion that the presence of extreme values, i.e. spurious outliers, may cause, indexes are sometime
constructed over a 98% winsorized distribution. This entails transforming the indicators below the 1st
percentile into values corresponding to the 1st percentile, and having the indicators above the 99th percentile
set to the 99th percentile.
Unless otherwise specified, technology fields are defined according to Schmoch’s (2008)
classification (as updated in 2010 and 2011) which relies on the International Patent Classification (IPC)
codes contained in the patent documents. This taxonomy features six main technology sectors, subdivided
into 35 fields of balanced size, structured so as to maximise within-sector homogeneity and across-sector
differences 75. Using alternative technology classifications would change the value of the indicators and the
statistics proposed.
The following sections describe the proposed thirteen indicators according to the same format. Each
time, an outline of the type of information provided by the indicator at hand is accompanied by the relevant
literature on which it relies. An operational definition of the indicator follows, as well as a brief description
of the way it has been constructed, and a discussion of possible challenges and shortcomings. Descriptive
statistics showing the value that the indicator takes over time and across countries and technology fields
complement this part.
The original working paper 76 (of which this chapter is an excerpt) contains the program codes used to
build the indicators and is accompanied by a database containing the indicators proposed, calculated at the
individual patent level. The working paper also includes a number of robustness tests aimed at better
understanding the behaviour of the indicator, as well as its sensitivity to alternative specifications.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
90 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Supplying the dataset and the program codes to compile the indicators aims at facilitating a peer
review of the indicators proposed, and trigger an open source-like development, whereby users might help
to fine-tune the indicators, test their robustness, and verify their ability to capture the economic and
technological value of patented inventions.
Patent scope
Background and definition
The scope of patents is often associated with the technological and economic value of patents. Lerner
(1994) observes that the technological breadth of patents in a firm’s portfolio significantly affects the
valuation of the firm, and that broad patents are more valuable when many possible substitutes in the same
product class are available. Matutes, Régibeau and Rockett (1996) also look at patent protection regimes,
and in particular at the length and scope 77 of patent protection, and suggest that the scope of a patent
should be used to foster the early disclosure of fundamental innovations.
The index proposed here follows Lerner (1994) and defines the scope of a patent in terms of the
number of distinct 4-digit subclasses of the International Patent Classification 78 the invention is allocated
to. For each patent document P, the patent scope index is defined as:
𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑆𝑃 = 𝑛𝑝 ; 𝑛 ∈ �𝐼𝐼𝐼14 ; … ; 𝐼𝐼𝐼𝑖4 ; 𝐼𝐼𝐼𝑗4 ; … ; 𝐼𝐼𝐼𝑛4 � & 𝐼𝐼𝐼𝑖4 ≠ 𝐼𝐼𝐼𝑗4 ,
where np denotes the number of distinct 4 digit IPC subclasses listed in the patent p document. Data refers
to the latest edition of the IPC (8th edition). The index is normalised according to the maximum scope value
of the patents in the same cohort, with cohorts being defined according to year of filing and technology
field. The larger the number of distinct 4-digit IPC classes, the broader the scope index, and the higher the
potential technological and market value of a patent 79.
Indicator overview
In PATSTAT, IPC codes of patent documents are converted into the latest available edition of the IPC
classification, i.e. 8th edition, entered into force in 2006. Patents based on previous editions of the IPC
classification have thus been re-classified accordingly. Also, due to the emergence of new technologies,
sometimes no one-to-one correspondence exists between old and new IPC editions, and older IPC codes
may correspond to many IPC 8th edition codes. Hence, patents filed before the mid-2000s may feature a
broader range of IPC-7 codes than later patents: five codes on average for patents filed in 2000 compared
to around 2.5 codes per patent in the late 2000s. As can be seen from the figure below, each IPC code in
force at the date of patenting has been allocated in PATSTAT to around two codes of the IPC 8th edition.
Figure 2.1.
Average number of IPC classes per EPO patent document, by IPC edition
Re-classification to IPC 8
Current IPC edition at publication
6
4
2
0
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012) and OECD, Patent database, October 2012.
As a consequence, the patent scope index tends to be overestimated before the mid-2000s. For
example, the patent scope index of micro- and nano-technology patents gets seemingly divided by three
between 1999 and 2009.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
91 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Patents in the pharmaceuticals, control-technologies or biotechnology fields conversely report the
largest indices in 2009, corresponding to 0.31, 0.29 and 0.26 respectively, as compared to 0.21 on average
observed for all patents. Australia, Canada, Japan and Finland rank above the world’s average patent scope
index in 2009.
Figure 2.2.
Patent Scope, index, 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
Patent Scope, average index by technology field
1999
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Patent Scope, average index by economy
2009
1999
2009
EPO patents, 2009
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
115888
8145
Australia
Canada
4305
3659
Japan
6469
Finland
865
6747
Singapore
Spain
971
3268
Sweden
2846
Denmark
5651
France
1209
Belgium
1722
8349
Luxembourg
4513
Switzerland
3751
Norway
5393
2886
Austria
965
3089
World average
Italy
2160
United Kingdom
1751
0.6
Netherlands
152
2693
Germany
1427
Ireland
3427
2719
India
3984
2027
China
United States
2883
2066
Brazil
3494
Chinese Taipei
4907
2043
2039
3313
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
Israel
Turkey
Korea
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
Note: The patent scope index is normalised according to the maximum scope value of the patents in the same cohort (filing date and
technology fields). The average by economy is provided only for economies reporting the index for more than 200 patents in 2009.
The small numbers on the right hand of the average by technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
92 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Patent family size
Background and definition
Owing to the Paris Convention (1883), applicants have up to 12 months from the first filing of a
patent application (typically in the country of origin) to file applications in other jurisdictions regarding the
same invention and claim the priority date of the first application. The set of patents filed in several
countries which are related to each other by one or several common priority filings is generally known as
patent family. The value of patents is held to be associated with the geographical scope of patent
protection, that is, with the number of jurisdictions in which patent protection has been sought (Lanjouw et
al., 1998) and large international patent families have been found to be particularly valuable (Harhoff et al.,
2003). Applicants might be willing to accept additional costs and delays of extending protection to other
countries only if they deem it worthwhile.
The size of patent families is proxied here by the number of patent offices at which a given invention
has been protected. Because of differences in the legal procedures of offices worldwide, and of the delays
that these might determine, patent family related indicators may suffer from timeliness. The family size
index presented here has been normalised with respect to the maximum value exhibited by other patents in
the same cohort, with cohorts that are determined by the pair technology–year.
Indicator overview
The statistics shown below relate to EPO patents only. Filing for a European patent allows obtaining
protection in all the countries designated in the European Patent Convention (EPC) that have been
indicated in the application. A granted EPO patent ultimately represents a "bundle" of national patents, and
needs to be validated by the different national patent offices for it to be protected in the designated EPC
member countries (OECD, 2009). Patents applications filed to the EPO are by their very nature more prone
to broader geographical coverage, i.e. exhibit larger patent families than patents applied for in national
patent offices. Hence, compiling patent family indicators over patents originated in e.g. Japan or the United
States would very likely lead to different results.
As knowledge about the size of a patent family depends on the delays of publication of the patent
offices involved, patent family indicators calculated on recent years may not provide an accurate picture of
the geographical breadth of patented inventions. Hence, although the normalised family size index shown
below seems to have increased over time, also and especially in recent years, the figures relating to 2004
onwards should be interpreted with care, as they may suffer from truncation. With respect to breadth of the
patent families of different technological fields, it emerges that, along with the patents in the micro- and
nano-technology fields, patents in the semi-conductors and basic communication technologies are, on
average, the most broadly protected worldwide, in 2004. Country-wise, data seems to suggest that patents
originating from Norway, Australia, Sweden and the Netherlands tend to get the most extensive coverage
worldwide (in 2004).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
93 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.3.
Family size, index, 1990-2009
Average
75th percentile
Median
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
Family size, average index by technology field
1994
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Family size, average index by economy
2004
1994
2004
EPO patents, 2004
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
124576
7349
Norway
Australia
6847
4802
Sweden
6290
Netherlands
1194
Luxembourg
7339
Ireland
805
3035
United States
3585
Korea
5703
1190
United Kingdom
1910
7826
Finland
5897
Canada
4559
Singapore
6049
3067
Denmark
1111
Switzerland
2693
France
2061
World total
1923
60
0.6
Israel
2942
1326
Belgium
3774
Japan
3086
Austria
3877
2955
China
3155
1642
Spain
Germany
3744
5443
2129
2017
3191
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
Italy
India
Chinese Taipei
0.5
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
Note: The family size index is normalised according to the maximum family size of the patents in the same cohort (filing date and
technology fields). The index has been winsorised to correct for extreme values. The average by economy, provided only for
economies with more than 200 patents reporting the index in 2004. The small numbers on the right hand of the average by
technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
94 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Grant lag
Background and definition
Recent evidence (Harhoff and Wagner, 2009; Régibeau and Rockett, 2010) suggests the existence of
an inverse relationship between the value of a patent and the length of the grant lag period - defined as the
time elapsed between the filing date of the application and the date of the grant. This literature puts
forward a revealed preference argument whereby applicants try to accelerate the grant procedure for their
most valuable patents, e.g. by means of well documenting their applications and following closely the
work of the patent office. Harhoff and Wagner (2009) find that more controversial claims lead to slower
grants and that well-documented applications are approved faster. In addition Régibeau and Rockett (2010)
suggest that the time required to reach a granting decision depends on the effort made by the filing party,
and remark the importance of accounting for the position of patents in the technology cycle. They conclude
that important patents are approved more quickly, and the granting delay decreases as industries move
from the early stage of their innovation cycle to later stages. Anecdotal evidence gathered from patent
examiners tends to support such empirical findings.
The grant lag index we propose builds on these recent insights. It relies on patents that are stratified
by year and technology field and is defined as follows: for each patent p, the grant lag index GrantPi is:
𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝑃𝑃 = 1 − ∆𝑡⁄𝑀𝑀𝑀(∆𝑡𝑖 )
where Δt is the number of days elapsing between application and granting date; and Max(Δti) is the
maximum number of days it has taken any patent belonging to the same cohort i to be granted. The
normalisation of the index attempts to control for the possible examination backlogs and increasing
workload that may characterise certain years. By construction, the grant lag index is highest when the
decision to grant has been taken very rapidly relative to the other patents in the cohort.
Indicator overview
The way the grant lag index has been constructed leads truncation to artificially lower the values of
the index for the last available years. For the latest cohorts in fact, e.g. from 2005, the maximum grant lag
that can be observed will never be larger than a few years, e.g. six years in the case of patents applied in
2005. This leads to grant lag index values that are seemingly much smaller than those observed in previous
years, where much larger variation characterises the time elapsed between the filing date of the application
and the date of the grant.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
95 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.4.
Grant lag, index, 1990-2009
Average
75th percentile
Median
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
Grant lag, average index by technology field
1994
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2007
2008
2009
Grant lag, average index by economy
2004
1994
EPO patents, 2004
45671
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
2006
2730
1587
1464
2188
455
1757
2004
Austria
France
Italy
Germany
Chinese Taipei
Switzerland
25
695
Belgium
1043
Spain
1863
Netherlands
311
South Africa
616
2746
1991
United Kingdom
1167
Norway
1589
World total
Brazil
1297
408
Luxembourg
961
China
768
Canada
663
25
1139
541
1980
1697
India
Finland
Japan
Sweden
Denmark
1885
1447
Korea
1470
Ireland
596
2136
Singapore
United States
3336
926
789
1380
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Israel
Australia
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
0.8
Note: The grant lag index is compiled according to the maximum grant lag of patents in the same cohort (filing date and technology
fields). The index has been winsorised to correct for extreme values. The average by economy is provided only for economies with
more than 50 patents reporting the index in 2004. The small numbers on the right hand of the average by technology table show the
number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
96 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Backward citations
Background and definition
In order to evaluate the novelty of the innovation seeking patent protection, patent applicants are
asked to disclose the prior knowledge on which they have relied. This entails listing the possible patents,
scientific work and other sources of knowledge at the basis of the invention. Such references, also called
backward citations, are then checked by the patent examiner during the technical examination. They can be
integrated by means of citing additional relevant prior art, or otherwise removed, if deemed unrelated to
the invention under exam (see Alcacer and Gittelman, 2006, in this respect). Backward citations are used to
assess an invention’s patentability and define the legitimacy of the claims stated in the patent application
(OECD, 2009). At the EPO, backward citations are classified according to their relevance for the patent
under exam. Of particular importance are “X” and “Y” citations, as they may question the inventive step of
the filed patent (X references if taken alone; Y references if combined with others).
Indicators based on the number of citations made to prior patents and prior non-patent literature in a
patent can help assess the degree of novelty of an invention and investigate knowledge transfers in terms of
citations networks (see e.g. Criscuolo and Verspagen, 2008). In addition, aggregating citation data at the
country, technology or firm level may be informative of the dynamics of the inventive process. Controlling
for self-citations - i.e. citations made to inventions belonging to the same agent – further allows assessing
the technological cumulativeness of a firm, i.e. the extent to which new inventions rely on the company’s
prior innovative activities. Backward citations either to the patent or to non-patent literature (e.g. scientific
papers) have been found to be positively related to the value of a patent (Harhoff et al., 2003). However,
large numbers of backward citations may signal the innovation to be more incremental in nature (Lanjouw
and Schankerman, 2001) 80. Finally, it is worth remarking that, as citation practices and disclosure rules
may differ across patent offices, indicators compiled from alternative data sources are generally not
comparable.
In the statistics shown below the number of backward citations per patent is normalised according to
the maximum value received by patents in the same year-and-technology cohort. References to non-patent
literature have been excluded from the count, whereas self-citations have not.
Indicator overview
The backward citation indicator does not suffer much from truncation, as backward citations are
typically included in the patent document within the first two years since application. The figure shown
below suggests that the distribution of the backward citation index is generally left skewed and that it does
not change much over time. Average values are always around 0.3 and 75th percentile values are
around 0.4. This implies that the average patent features 30% of the maximum number of backward
citations contained in the patents belonging to the same cohort. It further entails that the distribution of
backward citations has a very long right tail, as can also be seen from the 2009 figures shown below.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
97 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.5.
Backward citations index, 1990-2009
Average
75th percentile
Median
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
Backward citations index, average by technology field
1999
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Backward citations index, average by economy
2009
1999
2009
EPO patents, 2009
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
115888
China
8145
Luxembourg
4305
3659
Japan
6469
Turkey
865
Australia
6747
Finland
971
3268
Canada
2846
Sweden
5651
1209
Denmark
1722
8349
4513
Spain
3751
5393
2886
965
3089
2160
1751
152
2693
1427
3427
2719
3984
0.2
0.3
0.4
Norway
France
Belgium
Italy
Singapore
Israel
United Kingdom
Netherlands
2027
2883
2066
3494
Ireland
Brazil
Chinese Taipei
2043
Korea
2039
India
3313
0.1
Germany
World average
United States
4907
0.0
Austria
Switzerland
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
Note: The backward citations index is normalised according to the maximum family size of the patents in the same cohort (filing date
and technology fields). The index has been winsorised to correct for extreme values. The average by economy is provided only for
economies with more than 200 patents reporting the index in 2009. The small numbers on the right hand of the average by technology
table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
98 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Citations to non-patent literature (NPL)
Background and definition
Most patent applications include a list of references – citations – to earlier patents and to non-patent
literature (NPL), e.g. scientific papers that set the boundaries of patents’ claims for novelty, inventive
activity and industrial applicability. Non-patent literature consists of peer-reviewed scientific papers,
conference proceedings, databases (e.g. DNA structures, gene sequences, chemical compounds, etc.) and
other relevant literature. References are added to reflect the prior art that inventions have built upon.
Backward citations to NPL can be considered as indicators of the contribution of public science to
industrial technology (Narin et al., 1997). They may reflect how close a patented invention is to scientific
knowledge and help depict the proximity of technological and scientific developments (Callaert et al.,
2006). Cassiman et al. (2008) suggest that patents that cite science (i.e. NPL) may contain more complex
and fundamental knowledge, and this in turn may influence the generality of patents. Branstetter (2005)
further finds that patents citing NPL are of significantly higher value than patents that do not cite scientific
literature.
Indicator overview
The citation to NPL index is calculated here as the number of NPL citations included in a patent
divided by the maximum number of NPL citations of patents belonging to the same year and technology
cohort. The NPL index captures the relative importance of NPL citations in a patent document vis-à-vis the
other patents in its cohort. We further calculate a NPL share index which reflects the propensity of a patent
document to cite NPL relative to the whole prior art cited in that same document. This index has been
normalised, so that it always ranges between zero and one. References to certain types of NPL such as
patent abstracts and commercial patent databases have in both cases been excluded.
The NPL index and NPL share index do not suffer much from truncation – NPL citations represent a
subset of the backward citations included in a patent document. As the citations to NPL index chart shows,
the majority of patents generally do not cite any non-patent literature as prior art, the distribution of NPL
citations is skewed and it features a very long right tail. Over the 1998 to 2009 period relatively very few
patents cite NPL, and the 75th percentile values of the NPL index are often zero or anyway very close to
zero.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
99 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.6.
Citations to NPL, index, 1990-2009
Average
75th percentile
Median
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
The charts of NPL index by technology field and by country highlight that different technologies and
countries seemingly rely on non-patent literature to a different extent. This may mirror differences in
countries’ technological specialisations, and in the stage of development of technologies.
Citations to NPL, index, average by technology field
1999
Citations to NPL, index, average by economy
2009
1999
2009
EPO patents, 2009
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
0.00
Spain
115888
8145
Ireland
4305
3659
France
6469
Singapore
865
6747
Finland
Belgium
971
3268
Netherlands
2846
China
5651
Sweden
1209
Japan
1722
8349
Brazil
4513
Denmark
3751
Israel
5393
United Kingdom
2886
Canada
965
3089
Australia
2160
1751
World average
152
2693
1427
Germany
3984
Austria
2883
2066
3494
4907
2043
2039
3313
0.10
0.15
Norway
3427
2719
2027
0.05
India
Switzerland
0.20
Korea
United States
Chinese Taipei
Luxembourg
Italy
Turkey
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
Note: The NPL citation index is normalised according to the maximum family size of the patents in the same cohort (filing date and
technology fields). The index has been winsorized to correct for extreme values. The average by economy is provided only for
economies with more than 200 patents reporting the index in 2009. The small numbers on the right hand of the average by
technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
100 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Claims
Background and definition
Claims determine the boundaries of the exclusive rights of a patent owner, given that only the
technology or aspects covered in the claims can be legally protected and enforced. The number and content
of the claims thus determine the breadth of the rights conferred by a patent (OECD, 2009). Moreover, as
the structure of the patent fee is generally based on the number of claims contained in the document, a
large number of claims might also imply higher fees. Hence, the number of claims in a patent document
may not only reflect the technological breadth of a patent, but also its expected market value: the higher the
number of claims, the higher the expected value of the patent (Tong and Davidson, 1994; Lanjouw and
Schankerman, 2001 81, 2004).
We propose here a claim-based indicator that relies on EPO patent data stratified by year of filing and
technology field. We further construct an indicator of the number of claims over backward citations. We
do so following Lanjouw and Schankerman (2001b), who suggest that backward citations are a sign that a
patent belongs to a relatively well-developed technology area, and that property rights are less uncertain.
For brevity, we call this latter index the “adjusted” index.
In the statistics below the indicator of the number of claims per patent, as well as the indicator
capturing the number of claims over backward citations, has been normalised with respect to the maximum
value of the patents in the same cohort.
Indicator overview
The number of claims contained in a patent very much depends upon the rules and regulations of
different patent offices. Therefore, indicators relying on claims may vary depending on the data source
used. For instance, because of the one claim rule which prevailed in Japan until 1975, applications to the
Japan Patent Office still have a significantly lower number of claims than those of patents filed in other
offices. Moreover, the number of claims in a patent is influenced by the claim-related fees structure and the
changes that may have happened over the years. For instance, in the case of EPO patents, before 1st April
2008 excess claims fees amounting to EUR 45 were charged starting from the 11th claim. After that date,
excess claims fees have been raised to EUR 200 but charged starting from the 16th claim.
The claim indicator may be sensitive to truncation, given that claims are reviewed during the
examination process, e.g. claims may be dropped or redefined by examiners. Hence, latest patent cohorts,
where a relatively higher number of patents may still be under examination, may feature higher mean
values of the index.
Technology fields seem to vary in the average number of claims per patent. The same happens by the
time patent claims by country are considered. Caution should be used when comparing the 1999 and the
2009 figures, as higher averages of the normalised indicator (displayed below) might simply reflect the
different type of distributions that claims exhibit over time. For instance, on average biotech patents feature
22 claims per patent in 1999 and 13 in 2009, and the standard deviation of the distribution of claims is
above 16 in 1999 and 12 in 2009. Conversely, micro and nano-tech patents contain on average 20 claims in
1999 and only 12 in 2009, and the standard deviation of their distributions goes from 17 in 1999 to 8 in
2009.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
101 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.7.
Number of claims, index, 1990-2009
Average
75th percentile
Median
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
Claims, average index by technology field
1999
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Claims, average index by economy
2009
1999
2009
EPO patents, 2009
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
115465
Chinese Taipei
8119
4285
Germany
Ireland
3645
Canada
6414
865
Korea
6714
Belgium
970
3251
2835
United Kingdom
5636
1206
1713
8293
4497
3742
5381
Switzerland
Australia
Austria
Singapore
Italy
United States
2880
Netherlands
964
Luxembourg
3085
World average
2151
1750
Israel
152
Denmark
2686
France
1423
3410
2712
3973
2022
Finland
Spain
Norway
Brazil
2874
2063
3487
4891
2034
2036
3306
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
Japan
Sweden
China
India
Turkey
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
Note: The claims index is normalised according to the maximum family size of the patents in the same cohort (filing date and
technology fields). The index has been winsorized to correct for extreme values. The average by economy is provided only for
economies with more than 200 patents reporting the index in 2009. The small numbers on the right hand of the average by
technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
102 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.8.
Claims over backward citations index, 1990-2009
Average
75th percentile
Median
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
Claims over backward citations, average index by
technology field
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Claims over backward citations, average index
by economy
2009
1999
2009
EPO patents, 2009
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
108111
Chinese Taipei
7527
4003
Ireland
Canada
3415
5805
Korea
800
Singapore
5933
784
United Kingdom
3035
2742
Netherlands
5220
1078
1596
8174
4313
3419
5169
2863
930
3041
2094
France
Switzerland
World average
Italy
2596
Denmark
2609
Sweden
Australia
3385
Norway
1953
Spain
2720
India
1760
3323
Luxembourg
4619
Japan
1929
1870
2900
0.2
Israel
Finland
Austria
3291
0.1
Belgium
1701
136
1378
0.0
Germany
United States
0.3
China
Turkey
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
Note: The adjusted claims index is normalised according to the maximum family size of the patents in the same cohort (filing date and
technology fields). The index has been winsorized to correct for extreme values. The average by economy is provided only for
economies with more than 200 patents reporting the index in 2009. The small numbers on the right hand of the average by
technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
103 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Forward citations
Background and definition
The number of citations a given patent receives (forward citations) mirrors the technological
importance of the patent for the development of subsequent technologies, and also reflects, to a certain
extent, the economic value of inventions (see Trajtenberg, 1990; Hall, et al., 2005; Harhoff et al., 2003).
The guidelines for examination in the European Patent Office require that the references to prior art are
classified according to their relevance for the patent application in question. While prior art can be cited as
documents defining the non-infringing state of the art in a technology field, there also exist three types of
citations that restrict the patentability of a patent application. These are:
•
X citations: documents that are particularly important when taken alone, to the point that a claimed
invention cannot be considered novel (where “novel” means new, i.e. not previously known or
used by others);
•
I citations: documents that are particularly important when taken alone, to the point that a claimed
invention cannot be considered to involve an inventive step or to be non-obvious. The inventive
step/non-obvious requirement means that, to be patentable, an invention must not be an obvious
variation or combination of previously known subject matter and has to ‘adequately’ differ from
the state of the art 82;
•
Y citations: documents that are particularly relevant if combined with one or more documents of
the same category, as such a combination would be obvious to a person skilled in the art.
Forward citation counts presented here are based on EPO patents citations and take into account
patent equivalents – that is, patent documents protecting the same invention at several patent offices
(see Webb et al., 2005). Forward citations are counted over a period of five or seven years after the
publication date. Publication typically occurs 18 months after the filing date of the patent. The windows for
observation used should allow capturing the different citation patterns of the technology fields considered.
However, the 5/7 years citation lag decreases the timeliness of the indicator: only patents published up to
the mid 2000s can thus be considered.
Counts also include self-citations following the findings of Hall et al. (2005) suggesting that selfcitations are generally more valuable than citations from external patents. Statistics are shown both with
respect to the total number of citations received (all categories of citations) and for citations received as X,
I or Y. X-I-Y forward citations signal the cited patent to be of higher technological value. The number of
forward citations can be written as:
𝑃𝑖 +𝑇
∑𝑗∈𝐽(𝑡) 𝐶𝑗,𝑖 ; 𝑇 ≤ 5 or 𝑇 ≤ 7
𝐶𝐶𝐶𝑖,𝑇 = ∑𝑡=𝑃
𝑖
where CITi,T is the number of forward citations received by patent application i published in year Pi within
T years from its publication (in the present case, within five years). Cj,i is a dummy variable that gets value
1 if the patent document j is citing patent document i, and 0 otherwise. J(t) is the set of all patents
applications published in year t. The number of forward citations per patent has been normalised with
respect to the maximum value observed in the cohort (i.e. in the group of patents filed in the same year and
belonging to the same technology field).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
104 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Indicator overview
In the mid-2000s, new guidelines for EPO examiners recommended keeping to the legally most
relevant citations (i.e. to those potentially invalidating part of the application, i.e. X and Y citations) and to
reduce references to “the general state of the art” (type A citations).
Moreover, in 2012 EPO introduced the new citation category I in the PATSTAT database, to
distinguish those citations that are particularly relevant for the novelty of a patent (i.e. code X) from those
that are particularly important in order to assess the inventive step involved (i.e. code I).
Table 2.1. below shows all the search codes that can be attributed to a patent citation, according to
EPO rules. These encompass codes signalling the extreme relevance of prior art for the patent under
examination, as well as codes cited for a better understanding of the invention (i.e. code T).
Table 2.1. Search codes allocated to patent citations, EPO
X
Particularly relevant documents when taken alone (a claimed invention cannot be considered novel)
I
A
Particularly relevant documents when taken alone (a claimed invention cannot be considered to involve an
inventive step)
Particularly relevant documents if combined with one or more other documents of the same category – such a
combination being obvious to a person skilled in the art
Documents defining the general state of the art (but not belonging to X, I or Y)
O
Documents which refer to non-written disclosure
P
D
Intermediate documents - documents published between the date of filing of the application being examined
and the date of priority claimed
Documents relating to the theory or principle underlying the invention (documents which were published after
the filing date and are not in conflict with the application, but were cited for a better understanding of the
invention)
Potentially conflicting documents – Any patent document bearing a filing or priority date earlier than the filing
date of the application searched but published later than that date, and the content of which would constitute
prior art
Documents cited in the application (i.e. already mentioned in the description of the patent application)
L
Documents cited for other reasons (e.g. a document that may throw doubt on a priority claim)
Y
T
E
Note: Category “I” was introduced in 2012. The former X category was split up into 2 categories: X and I. Up to three codes can be
allocated to a citation (e.g. AD, XD, XP, YP, APD, XPD).
Source: EPO, PATSTAT data catalog, April 2012.
The forward citation index has decreased over time throughout the period considered, although the
statistics related to the last 5 to 7 years should be interpreted with care, due to truncation. The way median
and 75th percentile values behave signal that distributions have become progressively more dispersed over
time, and that only a very small subset of patents typically receives a large number of forward citations.
Moreover the charts by technology field and by country further highlight the substantial heterogeneity
that characterises forward citation patterns, and the changes that seem to have occurred over time. The
increasing number of patents filed over the years, coupled with the progressively greater dispersion of
forward citation distributions and the different maturity of the technology fields considered may help
explain the stylised facts that emerge.
Korea, Belgium, Italy, Switzerland and Spain appear as top scoring countries in terms of average
forward citation index by country for the year 2004 when all citations are taken into account as well as
when only X, I, and Y citations are considered. No similarly consistent picture can be obtained at the
technology field level, where “Computer technology” scores highest in terms of forward citation index in
2004 and “Surface technology, coating”, “Micro and nano-technologies” and “Mechanical elements”
appear the most cited when X, I, and Y citations only are considered.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
105 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.9.
Forward citations, index, 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
Forward citations, average index by technology field
1994
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Forward citations, average index by
economy
2004
1994
2004
EPO patents, 2004
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
0.00
124576
Korea
3191
Belgium
2017
2129
Italy
Switzerland
5443
3744
Spain
1642
3155
Germany
France
2955
3877
China
World average
3086
3774
Chinese Taipei
1326
Canada
2942
Finland
60
1923
Singapore
2061
Austria
2693
Luxembourg
1111
Sweden
3067
6049
4559
United States
Denmark
5897
India
7826
Netherlands
1910
United Kingdom
1190
5703
Russian Federation
3585
Ireland
3035
Israel
805
Norway
7339
1194
6290
4802
Australia
6847
Brazil
7349
0.05
0.10
South Africa
New Zealand
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.15
Note: The forward citations index is normalised according to the maximum family size of the patents in the same cohort (filing date
and technology fields). The index has been winsorised to correct for extreme values. The average by economy is provided only for
economies with more than 100 patents reporting the index in 2004. The small numbers on the right hand of the average by
technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
106 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.10.
Forward citations, citations received as X, I or Y, index, 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
Forward citations, received as X, I or Y,
average index by technology field
1994
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Forward citations, received as X, I or Y,
average index by economy
2004
1994
2004
EPO patents, 2004
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
0.00
124576
Korea
7349
Belgium
6847
Spain
4802
6290
Italy
1194
Switzerland
7339
Chinese Taipei
805
3035
Germany
Canada
3585
France
5703
1190
World average
1910
China
7826
Singapore
5897
Finland
4559
6049
Luxembourg
3067
United States
1111
Austria
2693
Sweden
2061
Denmark
1923
60
2942
Netherlands
United Kingdom
1326
3774
India
3086
Israel
3877
Ireland
2955
Russian Federation
3155
Norway
1642
3744
South Africa
5443
New Zealand
2129
Australia
2017
3191
0.05
0.10
0.15
Brazil
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
Note: The forward citations index is normalised according to the maximum family size of the patents in the same cohort (filing date
and technology fields). The index has been winsorised to correct for extreme values. The average by economy is provided only for
economies with more than 100 patents reporting the index in 2004. The small numbers on the right hand of the average by
technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
107 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Breakthrough inventions
Background and definition
Breakthrough inventions are high-impact innovations which serve as a basis for future technological
developments, new products or services. Breakthrough inventions have been found to be strongly
associated with entrepreneurial strategies and with further technological development, and are at the centre
of many recent studies.
Ahuja and Lampert (2001) explore the relationship between the organisation of established firms and
the creation of breakthrough inventions. To this end, they define breakthrough inventions as the top 1% of
cited patents (i.e. the most highly cited patents) and find that three organisation-related “traps” generally
hinder breakthrough inventions: the familiarity, the maturity and the propinquity traps 83. Srivastava and
Gnyawali (2011) investigate the tension between value creation and value protection, and find that the
quality and diversity of the technological resources of a firm are positively correlated with breakthrough
innovations. Kerr (2010) relies on Ahuja and Lampert’s definition of breakthrough invention in order to
investigate the speed at which clusters of technology-related inventions migrate spatially in the aftermath
of breakthrough inventions. He finds evidence in support of significantly higher patenting growth in cities
and technologies where breakthrough inventions have occurred. Finally, Popp at al. (2012) analyse the
return to R&D in some energy technology sectors and find, among other results, that high value (i.e.
breakthrough) patents may induce subsequent innovations in those sectors.
We follow here the definition of breakthrough invention à la Ahuja and Lampert, i.e. as the top
1% cited patents. Similarly to the way in which the different forward citation indicators have been
constructed, breakthrough inventions may also be identified by means of restricting the type of citations
considered to those coded as X, I and Y.
Statistics related to breakthrough indicators built on all citations, as well as on X, I and Y citations
only are shown below. Counts of breakthrough inventions are aggregated at the country and at the
technological field level using fractional counts.
Indicator overview
Being built on forward citations, the breakthrough invention indicators also suffer from timeliness: a 5
(or 7) year period after publication needs to be allowed to identify the top cited patents in a certain
technology field and year cohort.
From the figure below, it can be seen that the share of breakthrough patents in the total number of
patents has persistently decreased over time. This may be due to the distribution of patents across
technology fields and to the fact that a proportionally higher number of patents never get cited: as the
overall number of cited patents decreases, also the number of top 1% cited patents decreases.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
108 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.11.
%
Share of breakthrough patents in total, 1990-2009
Breakthrough patents
Breakthrough patents (X,I,Y)
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Technology fields seem to differ markedly with respect to the number of breakthrough inventions
they feature, with Japan, the United States, and Germany that most contribute to generate breakthrough
inventions. New entrants like Korea also appear in 2004.
Share of breakthrough patents in total,
by technology field (percentages)
1994
Share of economies in breakthrough patents,
percentages
2004
1994
Breakthrough patents, 2004
286
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
2004
Japan
20
17
United States
13
18
2
14
1.1
Germany
Korea
1
10
Switzerland
7
10
1
Netherlands
4
18
France
10
Italy
4
4
Finland
10
3
4
Canada
7
Austria
5
1.7
(1)
8
4
Sweden
Chinese Taipei
8
8
12
Spain
7
United Kingdom
8
5
Australia
7
18
Denmark
3
7
8
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Belgium
1
0
10
20
30
40
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012. The small numbers on the right hand of the
average by technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
109 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Generality index
Background and definition
Forward patent citations can be used to assess the range of later generations of inventions that have
benefitted from a patent, by means of measuring the range of technology fields – and consequently
industries - that cite the patent (Bresnahan and Trajtenberg, 1995). The patent generality index à la
Trajtenberg et al. (1997) has been used in a variety of studies aimed to e.g. identify general purpose
technologies (Hall and Trajtenberg, 2004); investigate the role of universities as sources of commercial
technologies (Henderson et al., 1998); study participation and rent sharing in patent pools (Layne-Farrar
and Lerner, 2011); and understand the functioning of the market for innovation and the way patent rights
are enforced (Galasso et al, 2011).
The patent generality index proposed here is based on a modification of the Hirschman-Herfindahl
Index (HHI) and relies on information concerning the number and distribution of citations received
(forward citations) and the technology classes (IPC) of the patents these citations come from. Differently
from the way in which generality has been calculated in previous studies (e.g. Hall et al, 2001b) we
consider all IPC classes contained in the citing patent documents and account for the number and
distribution of both 4-digit and n-digit IPC technology classes contained in citing patents, where n refers to
the highest level of disaggregation possible (e.g. A61K 31/5575). Citation measures are built on EPO
patents and patent equivalents have been consolidated. Forward citations cover all categories of citations,
and are restricted to a 5-year citation window.
Let X be the focal patent with Yi patents citing the focal patent X, with i = 1, ….., N and let 𝛽𝑗𝑗 be
defined as follows:
𝛽𝑗𝑗 =
𝑛
𝑇𝑗𝑗
𝑇𝑖𝑛
𝑇𝑖𝑛 is the total number of IPC n-digit classes in yi
where
𝑇𝑗𝑗𝑛 is the total number of of IPC n-digit classes in the jth IPC4 digit class in yi
and
j=1… Mi is the cardinal of all IPC4-digit classes in yi
Our generality index is defined as:
n
𝑇𝑗𝑗
As 𝛽𝑗𝑗 =
𝑇𝑖n
1
𝑀𝑖
� ∑𝑁
𝐺𝑋 = 1 − ∑𝑗=1
𝑖=1 𝛽𝑗𝑗 �
, the generality index can be rewritten as:
𝑁
1
𝑀𝑖
� ∑𝑁
𝐺𝑋 = 1 − ∑𝑗=1
𝑖=1
Which has a denominator equal to 𝑇𝑖𝑛 ∗ 𝑁.
𝑁
𝑛
𝑇𝑗𝑗
2
2
𝑛�
𝑇𝑖
Indicator overview
The proposed generality index is defined between zero and one, and the measure is high if a patent is
cited by subsequent patents belonging to a wide range of fields – i.e. the considered invention has been
relevant for a number of later inventions, and not only in its own technology class. Conversely, if most
citations are concentrated in a few fields the generality index is low, i.e. close to zero. As suggested by
Hall et al. (2001a), the generality measure may be biased when the number of patents on which it is based
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
110 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
is small. However, as we account for all IPC n-digit classes contained in the citing patent documents our
denominator becomes 𝑇𝑖𝑛 ∗ 𝑁, and our generality indicator suffers less from this small number of
observation bias.
Generality measures strongly depend on the patent classification scheme used: the finer the level of
classification the higher the measures. Moreover, the generality index treats technologies that are closely
related but are not in the same class in the same way as they treat very distant technology fields. This may
lead to overestimate or underestimate the generality of patents (Hall and Trajtenberg, 2004).
Figure 2.12.
Generality index, 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Generality Index, average by technology field
1994
2004
1994
EPO patents, 2004
25193
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
0.0
Generality Index, average by economy
2004
Finland
1728
1624
Belgium
Denmark
1165
1357
India
188
1273
United States
80
Netherlands
642
820
Ireland
1152
Japan
126
United Kingdom
416
1338
World average
Canada
762
406
Germany
587
717
Switzerland
Spain
206
565
Sweden
463
393
Luxembourg
13
Australia
488
321
816
France
Israel
650
Korea
1083
Italy
691
673
Austria
448
Singapore
892
1553
445
China
Chinese Taipei
462
649
0.2
0.4
0.6
Norway
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Note: The average by economy is provided only for economies with more than 20 patents reporting the index in 2004.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012. The small numbers on the right hand of the
average by technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
111 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Originality index
Background and definition
Patent originality refers to the breadth of the technology fields on which a patent relies. The patent
originality measure, first proposed by Trajtenberg et al. (1997), operationalises this concept of knowledge
diversification and its importance for innovation: inventions relying on a large number of diverse
knowledge sources (i.e. on patents belonging to a wide array of technology fields) are supposed to lead to
original results. Patent originality has been used in a wide range of studies, e.g. on the creation of venturebacked start-ups (Gompers et al., 2005); the duration and outcome of the patent examination procedure at
the European Patent Office (Harhoff and Wagner, 2009); and the value of post-merger patents vis-à-vis
pre-merger ones (Stahl, 2010).
Building on Hall at al. (2001b), we define the originality indicator as:
𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑂𝑃 = 1 − �
𝑛𝑝
𝑗
𝑠𝑝𝑝 2
where spj is the percentage of citations made by patent p to patent class j out of the np IPC 4-digit (or 7digit) patent codes contained in the patents cited by patent p. Citation measures are built on EPO patents
and account for patent equivalents.
The construction of the patent originality indicator follows a logic that is very similar to the one used
to construct the generality index, the main difference being that generality measures rely on forward
citations, whereas originality relies on backward cites. The specification proposed here further
differentiates the generality and the originality indicators, as the former accounts for the distribution of 7digit subclasses within the 4 digit classes they belong to, as well as for the distribution of the 4-digit classes
contained in citing documents; whereas the latter only accounts for the distribution of citations made at the
4-digit (or 7-digit, in the alternative specification proposed) level.
Indicator overview
Differently from Hall at al. (2001b), we rely on all the IPC classes contained in the patent documents
that the focal patent cites, and compute the indicator at the 8-digit level. We do so in order to minimise the
bias typically arising when the number of citations is small.
The figures below show statistics related to the patent originality index, i.e. to values of the patent
originality indicator normalised with respect to the maximum value of patents in the same technology and
year cohort. As can be seen, patent originality index values and distributions seem to have remained pretty
stable over the years, although denoting a progressive small increase. This is not true however for the
different technology fields, which appear to vary greatly in the extent to which they rely or broad or narrow
prior art. Country specific differences in the average values of the index also emerge, although they are not
as marked as those noted by technology field. It is also worth noticing that both the indices by sector and
those by country barely change between 1999 and 2009.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
112 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.13.
Originality index, 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
1.00
0.80
0.60
0.40
0.20
0.00
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Originality, average index by technology field
1999
Originality, average index by economy
2009
1999
EPO patents, 2009
108395
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
2009
India
7549
Japan
4021
3421
Israel
5832
Canada
800
5956
China
Australia
784
3045
United States
2752
5230
1079
World average
1602
Switzerland
Finland
8223
Belgium
4325
Denmark
3419
5170
2869
Netherlands
United Kingdom
930
Spain
3043
2101
Germany
1702
Luxembourg
136
France
2601
1379
Sweden
3305
2613
Austria
3395
Singapore
1957
2728
Korea
Norway
1760
3329
Ireland
4632
1937
Italy
1868
Chinese Taipei
Turkey
2902
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Note: The average by economy is provided only for economies with more than 200 patents reporting the index in 2009. The small
numbers on the right hand of the average by technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
113 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Radicalness index
Background and definition
Although the concept of radicalness may appear intuitive and easy to grasp, as it evokes something
completely different from what exists, defining and measuring the technological radicalness of inventions
remains challenging. An index of patent radicalness has been proposed by Shane (2001), where the
radicalness of a patent is measured as a time invariant count of the number of IPC technology classes in
which the patents cited by the given patent are, but in which the patent itself is not classified. He argues
that the more a patent cites previous patents in classes other than the ones it is in, the more the invention
should be considered radical, as it builds upon paradigms that differ from the one to which it is applied.
This definition has been adapted in this paper to account for the relative weight of each 4-digit
technology class contained in the cited patents. The indicator has further been normalised with respect to
the total number of IPC classes listed in the backward citations, so that its value ranges from zero to one.
This entails that the overall number of citations, i.e. the denominator of the index, corresponds to the count
of citations at the most disaggregated level available, e.g. H05B 41/231. The numerator instead reflects the
number of the IPC 4-digit classes contained in the cited documents, weighted by the times these classes
appear at the more disaggregated level. The OECD radicalness indicator à la Shane is therefore compiled
as follows:
𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑃 = �
𝑛𝑝
𝑗
𝐶𝐶𝑗 �𝑛𝑝 ; 𝐼𝐼𝐶𝑝𝑝 ≠ 𝐼𝐼𝐼𝑝
where CTj denotes the count of IPC-4 digit codes IPCpj of patent j cited in patent p that is not allocated to
patent p, out of n IPC classes in the backward citations counted at the most disaggregated level available
(up to the 5th hierarchical level). The higher the ratio, the more diversified the array of technologies on
which the patent relies upon.
Indicator overview
The indicator proposed by Shane (2001) is fundamentally backward-looking in nature as it captures
the radicalness of a patent in terms of the extent to which it differs from the predecessors it relies upon. It
nevertheless remains silent about whether a patent is also radical compared to other patents filed in the
same field during the very same period – that is whether it is ‘unique’ compared to contemporaneous
inventions – and with respect to the change that the invention might have brought about in terms of
subsequent technological developments.
Dahlin and Behrens (2005) conversely propose a definition of radicalness that relies on the novelty,
uniqueness and impact on future technological developments that patented inventions might have. They
analyse the citation patterns observed before, during and after the filing of a patent, in order to assess
whether it can be considered a radical invention. However the indicator they propose is binary in nature,
i.e. a patent is considered radical or not, and does not assess the degree of radicalness of an invention.
Continuous indicators rather than discrete ones nevertheless prove extremely useful to assess, among
others, the overall value of patent portfolios, and the innovative activity and output of firms over time. The
OECD is currently working with external experts to propose and operationalise a definition of radicalness
that builds on Dahlin and Behrens’ work and takes into account radicalness with respect to previous,
contemporaneous and future developments. The ultimate goal is to construct a continuous radicalness
indicator that can be calculated for all patents. Waiting for these new developments, the indicator shown
below follows the radicalness definition by Shane (2001).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
114 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.14.
Radicalness index, 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
Radicalness, average index by technology field
1999
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Radicalness, average index by economy
2009
1999
2009
EPO patents, 2009
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
115888
Israel
8145
4305
United States
Netherlands
3659
6469
Canada
865
Denmark
6747
World average
971
Ireland
3268
China
2846
5651
Japan
1209
Belgium
1722
France
8349
4513
Austria
3751
5393
Germany
Finland
2886
965
3089
2160
Switzerland
United Kingdom
Brazil
1751
Luxembourg
152
2693
Sweden
Korea
1427
Australia
3427
2719
India
3984
Spain
2027
Norway
2883
2066
Turkey
3494
Italy
4907
2043
Singapore
2039
Chinese Taipei
3313
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.8
Note: The average by economy is provided only for economies with more than 200 patents reporting the index in 2009. The small
numbers on the right hand of the average by technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
115 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Patent renewal
Background and definition
The renewal of a patent signals that the invention described in the patent document is still useful, i.e.
that it has some value, as no rational agent would be willing to pay money for a right that is worthless.
Information about the renewal of patents has been used in a wide array of studies, which generally
suggest that more valuable patents are renewed for longer periods (e.g. Pakes, 1986). Following the
pioneering work of Pakes and Schankerman (1984), patent renewal data have been used to estimate the
private value of patent protection. These models rely on the assumption that patent owners make profitmaximising renewal decisions, and that patent renewals’ rates can be used to estimate the private value of
patent protection. Patent renewal data have also been used to weight patent counts, and to obtain more
precise measures of innovative output. This is the path followed by e.g. Lanjouw, Pakes and Putnam
(1998), who hold that more valuable inventions generate larger and/or longer lived patent families. More
recently, Svensson (2012) investigates the relationship that exists between the commercialisation and the
renewal of patents, and finds a positive correlation between commercialisation and the use of patents for
defensive purposes on the one hand and patent renewal on the other hand. He further finds that the value of
patents influences both commercialisation and renewal decisions.
The OECD patent renewal indicator corresponds to the simple count of years during which a granted
patent has been kept alive, i.e. the latest year in which it has been renewed or until it has lapsed or has been
withdrawn. Years are counted starting from the year in which a patent has been applied.
Indicator overview
The box 2.1. below highlights the patent codes used to measure patent renewal. In the case of patent
renewals no robustness checks are presented, as the indicator is the simple count of years during which a
patent has been renewed.
Box 2.1. Identifying the length of patent renewal
The EPO worldwide legal status database (INPADOC) contains information related to any administrative act or action
concerning a patent document, from application onwards, including the post-grant phase. A variety of codes is typically
allocated to each legal event, as it depends on the specific patent authority responsible for the act or action. The codes
listed below refer to events related to EPO patent applications only. For alternative patent authorities, other codes
apply.
List of events relating to the length of EPO patent renewal in the INPADOC legal status database
The life duration of a patent can be assessed by the latest legal event that occurred, namely the withdrawal, the
renewal (payment of fees) or the lapse of patents. Hence, it is critical to respect the events’ chronology for each patent
in the database.
•
Granted EPO patent: Publn_first_grant = 1 (in PATSTAT, PAT_PUBLN table);
•
Renewed EPO patent: prs_code = PGFP (annual fees paid to national office) and latest payment date;
•
•
Withdrawn EPO patent: prs_code = 18D (patent deemed withdrawn) or prs_code = 18W (patent
withdrawn) and either date in force or withdrawal date variables; D18D and D18W codes cancel the former
18D and 18W events. If any D18D or D18W event occurred after 18D or 18W, then the patent is not
considered as withdrawn;
Lapsed EPO patent: prs_code = PG25 (lapsed in a contracting state announced via postgrant information
from national office to EPO) and earliest date in force.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
116 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.15.
Share of patents renewed at least 5 or 7 years in total granted patents, 1978-2009
%
At least 7 years
At least 5 years
100
75
50
25
0
Patent renewal, average duration of patents
in number of years, by technology field
1978
Patent renewal, average duration of patents
in number of years, by economy
1988
1978
1988
EPO patents, 1988
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
49743
Japan
2914
Norway
2161
1037
347
Ireland
Denmark
779
1530
World average
21
Belgium
1156
1894
2638
Sweden
402
United States
733
France
2020
3239
Switzerland
1508
1649
Netherlands
2567
Austria
512
Germany
1581
1539
Australia
948
Finland
1481
Canada
682
United Kingdom
1991
Italy
1711
1402
Israel
1706
2019
Luxembourg
659
Spain
1762
South Africa
1887
891
787
1589
0
5
10
Hungary
Chinese Taipei
15
0
5
10
15
Note: The average by economy is provided only for economies with more than 50 patents filed in 1998 and renewed. The small
numbers on the right hand of the average by technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012) and INPADOC Legal Status (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
117 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
The top figure above shows the percentage of patents renewed for at least 5 (or 7) years, by year
cohort. This is done to minimise the effect of truncation over the statistics proposed, as patents have a life
of up to 20 years.
Patent value: composite index
Background and definition
Patent value indicators try to capture both the technological and the economic value of innovations,
and are typically based on patent citations, claims, patent renewals and patent family size. They are
considered meaningful measures of research productivity and are found to be correlated with the social and
private value of the patented inventions. The difference in average patent value across firms is generally
associated with the market’s evaluation of firms, including their market capitalisation, the assessments
made by financing institutions and prospective acquirers, and so on.
The patent value composite index presented here is an experimental one and may be subject to further
refinement. The patent value index is a composite indicator based on four to six dimensions of patents’
underlying value: forward citations; patent family size; number of claims; generality index; plus backward
citations and grant lag. It builds on Lanjouw and Shankerman (2004) and incorporates the generality
measure, and a measure accounting for the length of the examination process (i.e. the grant lag index). All
components are normalised according to patent cohorts stratified by year and technological field and are
given equal importance (no weights).
Three alternative definitions of the experimental patent value indicator are proposed, in order to better
see the impact of the grant lag index and the backward citations index on the indicator:
i.
Patent value index 4 – 4 components: number of forward citations (up to 5 years after
publication); patent family size; number of claims; and the patent generality index. Only granted
patents are covered by the index.
ii.
Patent value index 4b – 4 components, bis: number of forward citations (up to 5 years after
publication); patent family size; corrected claims; and the patent generality index. Only granted
patents are covered by the index.
iii.
Patent value index 6 – 6 components: covers the same components as above, plus the number of
backward citations and the grant lag index.
Indicator overview
As the patent value measure proposed is based on indicators like forward citations and grant lags, it
suffers from timeliness. It should also be noted that using alternative data sources, e.g. US Patent and
Trademark Office or Japan Patent Office, different methodologies or observation periods may affect
patents’ scores, countries’ rank and sectors’ positions.
The three specifications proposed exhibit somewhat different time trends, although not marked ones.
Whatever the specification though, micro and nano technologies seemingly feature the highest patent value
- although the numbers rely on a very small set of observations. South Africa, Australia, Canada, Norway
and the United Kingdom appear as top patent value countries according to all specifications proposed.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
118 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.16.
Patent Value Index (4) Index, 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Patent Value Index (4), average by technology field
1994
Patent Value Index (4), average by economy
2004
1994
2004
EPO patents, 2004
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
0.0
45671
South Africa
2730
Australia
1587
1464
2188
Canada
Norway
455
1757
United Kingdom
Denmark
25
Ireland
695
1043
1863
Korea
Sweden
311
United States
616
2746
Finland
1991
Luxembourg
1167
1589
1297
France
408
Netherlands
Israel
961
Switzerland
768
663
Italy
Belgium
25
1139
World average
541
1980
Brazil
Singapore
1697
1885
Japan
1447
1470
Spain
China
596
2136
India
3336
0.1
0.2
0.3
Germany
926
789
Austria
1380
Chinese Taipei
0.4
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
Note: The patent value composite index is based on the average value of its normalised component, by cohort of filing date and
technology fields. The average by economy is provided only for economies with more than 50 patents reporting the index in 2004.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012. The small numbers on the right hand of the
average by technology table show the number of observations on which statistics rely.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
119 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.17.
Patent Value Index (4b), 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Patent Value Index (4b), average by technology field
1994
2004
1994
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
0.0
Patent Value Index (4b), average by economy
2004
South Africa
Norway
United Kingdom
Canada
Sweden
Korea
Denmark
Finland
Australia
United States
France
Ireland
Luxembourg
Netherlands
Switzerland
Israel
Italy
Belgium
World average
Brazil
Japan
India
Singapore
Spain
Germany
China
Austria
Chinese Taipei
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.4
Note: The patent value composite index is based on the average value of its normalised component, by cohort of filing date and
technology fields. The average by economy is provided only for economies with more than 50 patents reporting the index in 2004.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
120 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Figure 2.18.
Patent Value Index (6), 1990-2009
Average
Median
75th percentile
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Patent Value Index (6), average by technology field
1994
Patent Value Index (6), average by economy
2004
1994
2004
EPO patents, 2004
All sectors
Electrical machinery
Audio-visual technology
Telecommunications
Digital communication
Basic communication
Computer technology
IT methods for management
Semiconductors
Optics
Measurement
Biological materials
Control
Medical technology
Organic fine chemistry
Biotechnology
Pharmaceuticals
Macromolecular chemistry
Food chemistry
Basic materials chemistry
Materials, metallurgy
Surface technology, coating
Micro & nano-technology
Chemical engineering
Environmental technology
Handling
Machine tools
Engines, pumps, turbines
Textile and paper machines
Other special machines
Thermal processes and apparatus
Mechanical elements
Transport
Furniture, games
Other consumer goods
Civil engineering
0.0
South Africa
Canada
Norway
United Kingdom
France
Italy
Luxembourg
Denmark
Korea
Finland
United States
Australia
Sweden
Ireland
Netherlands
World average
Switzerland
Belgium
Austria
Israel
Germany
China
Japan
Spain
Brazil
Singapore
Chinese Taipei
India
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
Note: The patent value composite index is based on the average value of its normalised component, by cohort of filing date and
technology fields. The average by economy is provided only for economies with more than 50 patents reporting the index in 2004.
Source: OECD, calculations based on PATSTAT (EPO, April 2012), October 2012.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
121 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
It should be noticed that the original formulation of Lanjouw and Schankerman (2004) weighted the
different components of the composite indicator using factor analysis. The OECD experimental patent
value indicators conversely assume all components to play an equally important role, i.e. they are assigned
equal weights. This choice is motivated by the results of the exploratory analysis carried out when
designing the indicator, which suggests that weights differ across technology fields and depend on the time
span considered. Hence, for comparability purposes the composite value indicators presented here assign
equal importance to all components, and we leave it to future empirical analysis to determine the
coefficients that would best mirror the relative importance of the different value factors.
Needless to say, while the experimental OECD indicator tries to summarise a complex and
multidimensional issue like patent value, it nevertheless suffers from the typical drawbacks of all
composite indicators, and should therefore be interpreted with care 84.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
122 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
ANNEX TECHNOLOGY FIELDS
The IPC-Technology concordance table developed by the WIPO in 2010 and revised in 2011 has been
used to group patents by main technology fields. The taxonomy is articulated in 6 sectors and 35 fields, as
follows:
1. Electrical engineering
1. Electrical machinery, apparatus, energy
2. Audio-visual technology
3. Telecommunications
4. Digital communication
5. Basic communication processes
6. Computer technology
7. IT methods for management
8. Semiconductors
2. Instruments
9. Optics
10. Measurement
11. Analysis of biological materials
12. Control
13. Medical technology
3. Chemistry
14. Organic fine chemistry
15. Biotechnology
16. Pharmaceuticals
17. Macromolecular chemistry, polymers
18. Food chemistry
19. Basic materials chemistry
20. Materials, metallurgy
21. Surface technology, coating
22. Micro-structural and nano-technology
23. Chemical engineering
24. Environmental technology
4. Mechanical engineering
25. Handling
26. Machine tools
27. Engines, pumps, turbines
28. Textile and paper machines
29. Other special machines
30. Thermal processes and apparatus
31. Mechanical elements
32. Transport
5. Other fields
33. Furniture, games
34. Other consumer goods
35. Civil engineering
Source: WIPO, 2011.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
123 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
NOTES
73.
74.
75.
76.
77.
78.
79.
80.
81.
82.
83.
84.
Among the many initiatives discussing these issues there have been the Knowledge Networks and Markets
(KNM) “Expert Workshop on Patent Practice and Innovation” organised at the OECD in May 2012, and
the Patent Quality Workshop organised in May 2012 by the European Patent Office's (EPO) Economic and
Scientific Advisory Board (ESAB), in which the OECD participated. The report of the EPO-ESAB
workshop can be found at www.epo.org/about-us/office/esab/workshops.html
Non-practicing entities, also known as patent assertion entities, are firms that hold patents that they do not
use in order to produce or “practice” (i.e. “non-practicing” or “non-competing” firms). See Geradin at al.
(2012) for a discussion about non-practicing entities and their possible role as patent owners.
Annex 1 lists the technology fields considered, whereas a detailed list of the IPC classes contained in each
technology field can be found at www.wipo.int/ipstats/en/statistics/patents/pdf/wipo_ipc_technology.pdf
Mariagrazia Squicciarini, Hélène Dernis & Chiara Criscuolo, “Measuring Patent Quality: Indicators of
Technological and Economic Value,” OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2013/03,
available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k4522wkw1r8-en.
The definition of scope in Matutes et al. (1996) differs from Lerner’s (1994) and refers to both legal- and
product-related aspects. In terms of product definition, scope refers to the type of protection granted to the
innovator with respect to the possible uses of the basic technology.
The International Patent Classification provides for a hierarchical system for the classification of patents
and utility models according to the areas of technology they pertain to. See
www.wipo.int/classifications/ipc/en
The definition of scope adopted here is completely unrelated to the extent to which claims may be narrowly
or broadly defined, as the word ‘scope’ may also seem to imply.
Harhoff et al. (2003) explicitly discuss this argument with patent lawyers and examiners and find them not
to be supportive of it.
Lanjouw and Schankerman (2001a) investigate the cost of engaging in litigations over intellectual property
assets and find that patents with more claims and more citations by subsequent patentees are substantially
more likely to be involved in litigations. They suggest patent claims to be an indicator of the value of
patents and of the technology or product "space" protected by the patent.
The term “inventive step” is predominantly used in Europe, while “non-obviousness" is predominantly
used in the United States.
The familiarity trap refers to favouring familiar technological solutions over unfamiliar ones; the maturity
trap refers to favouring mature technologies over emerging ones; the propinquity trap is a condition that
relates to the originality of the technological solution used, and consists in trying to modify an available
technology rather than focusing on novel solutions.
See OECD and EC-JRC 2008 manual on composite indicators for an exhaustive discussion.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
124 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
REFERENCES
Alcacer, J. and M. Gittelman (2006), “Patent Citations as a Measure of Knowledge Flows: The Influence
of Examiner Citations”, The Review of Economics and Statistics 88(4): 774–779.
Ahuja, G. and C.M. Lampert (2001), “Entrepreneurship in the Large Corporation: A Longitudinal Study of
How Established Firms Create Breakthrough Inventions”, Strategic Management Journal 22 (6-7):
521-543.
Branstetter L. (2005), “Exploring the Link between Academic Science and Industrial Innovation”, Annals
of Economics and Statistics, 79/80: 119-142.
Bresnahan T. F and M. Trajtenberg (1995), “General Purpose Technologies. ‘Engines of Growth’?”,
Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 65: 83-108.
Callaert J., B. Van Looy, A. Verbeek, K. Debackere, and B. Thijs (2006), “Traces of Prior Art: An
Analysis of Non-Patent References Found in Patent Documents”, Scientometrics, 69(1): 3-20.
Cassiman, B., R.Veugelers, and P. Zuniga (2008). “In search of performance effects of (in)direct industry
science links”, Industrial and Corporate Change, 17(4): 611–646.
Criscuolo, P. and B. Verspagen (2008), “Does it Matter where Patent Citations Come from? Inventor vs.
Examiner Citations in European Patents”, Research Policy, Elsevier, No. 37 (10): 1892-1908.
Dahlin, K. and D. Behrens (2005), “When is an Invention Really Radical? Defining and Measuring
Technological Radicalness”, Research Policy, Elsevier, No. 34 (2005): 717–737.
European Patent Office (2012). “Report – Workshop on Patent Quality Initiated by the EPO Economic and
Scientific Advisory Board. 7 May 2012, European Patent Office, Munich”.
www.epo.org/about-us/office/esab/workshops.html (last visited October 2012).
Galasso, A., Schankerman, M., and C. J. Serrano (2011). “Trading and Enforcing Patent Rights”. NBER
Working Papers No. 17367, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.,
www.nber.org/papers/w17367 (Revised August 2012).
Geradin D., Layne-Farrar A., and A. J. Padilla (2012). “Elves or Trolls? The Role of Nonpracticing Patent
Owners in the Innovation Economy”, Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 21(1): 73–94.
Gompers, P., Lerner, J., and D. Scharfstein (2005). “Entrepreneurial Spawning: Public Corporations and
the Genesis of New Ventures, 1986 to 1999”, The Journal of Finance, 60(2), 577-614.
Guellec, D., and B. van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie (2007). “The Economics of the European Patent
System: IP Policy for Innovation and Competition”. Oxford University Press, Oxford (UK).
Hall, B. H., Graham S. J. H., Harhoff D., and D. C. Mowery (2003). “Prospects for Improving U.S. Patent
Quality via Post-Grant Opposition”, NBER Working Papers No. 9731, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Inc., www.nber.org/papers/w9731.
Hall, B. H., and D. Harhoff (2012). “Recent Research on the Economics of Patents”. NBER Working
Papers No. 17773, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., www.nber.org/papers/w17773
Hall, B.H., Jaffe A. and M. Trajtenberg (2001a), “Market Value and Patent Citations: A First Look”,
Economics Department Working Paper E00-277, University of California.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
125 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Hall, B.H., Jaffe A. and M. Trajtenberg (2001b), “The NBER Patent Citation Data File: Lessons, Insights
and Methodological Tools”, NBER Working Papers No. 8498, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Inc., www.nber.org/papers/w8498.
Hall, B.H., Jaffe A. and M. Trajtenberg (2005), “Market Value and Patent Citations”, Rand Journal of
Economics, No. 36, Spring.
Hall, B.H., and M. Trajtenberg (2004), “Uncovering GPTS with Patent Data”, NBER Working Papers,
No. 10901, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., www.nber.org/papers/w10901.
Harhoff, D., and S. Wagner (2009), “The Duration of Patent Examination at the European Patent Office”,
Management Science, Vol. 55 (12): 1969-1984.
Harhoff, D., F. M. Scherer, and K. Vopel (2003), “Citations, Family Size, Opposition and the Value of
Patent Rights”, Research Policy, 32(8): 1343-1363.
Henderson, R., Jaffe, A. and M. Trajtenberg (1998). "Universities as a Source of Commercial Technology:
A Detailed Analysis of University Patenting, 1965-1988." Review of Economics and Statistics,
80(1): 119-27.
Kerr, W. R. (2010). “Breakthrough Inventions and Migrating Clusters of Innovation”, Journal of Urban
Economics, 67(1): 46-60.
Lanjouw J. O., A. Pakes, and J. Putnam (1998), “How to Count Patents and Value Intellectual Property:
The Uses of Patent Renewal and Application Data”, Journal of Industrial Economics, 46(4): 405432.
Lanjouw, J. O. and M. Schankerman (2001a), “Characteristics of Patent Litigation: A Window on
Competition”, RAND Journal of Economics, 32(1): 129-151
Lanjouw, J. O. and M. Schankerman (2001b), “Enforcing Intellectual Property Rights”. NBER Working
Papers No. 8656, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., www.nber.org/papers/w8656 .
Lanjouw, J. and M. Schankerman (2004), “Patent Quality and Research Productivity: Measuring
Innovation with Multiple Indicators”, The Economic Journal, 114(495): 441-465.
Layne-Farrar, A., and J. Lerner (2011). “To Join or not to Join: Examining Patent Pool Participation and
Rent Sharing Rules”. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29(2): 294–303.
Lerner, J. (1994), “The Importance of Patent Scope: An Empirical Analysis”, RAND Journal of
Economics, 25(2): 319-333.
Matutes, C, P. Regibeau, and K. Rockett (1996), “Optimal Patent Design and the Diffusion of
Innovations”, RAND Journal of Economics, 27 (1): 60-83.
Martinez, C. (2010), “Insight into Different Types of Patent Families”, OECD Science, Technology and
Industry Working Papers, No. 2010/2, OECD, Paris.
Narin, F., K.S. Hamilton, and D. Olivastro (1997), “The increasing linkage between U.S. technology and
public science”. Research Policy, 26: 317-330
OECD and European Union, Joint Research Centre- European Commission (2008), Handbook on
Constructing Composite Indicators: Methodology and User Guide. OECD Publishing, Paris. DOI:
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264043466-en .
OECD
(2009),
OECD
Patent
Statistics
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264056442-en.
Manual,
OECD
Publishing,
Paris.
Doi:
Pakes, A. (1986), “Patents as Options: Some Estimates of the Value of Holding European Patent Stocks”,
Econometrica, 54(4): 755-784.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
126 | MEASURING THE TECHNOLOGICAL AND ECONOMIC VALUE OF PATENTS
Pakes, A. and M. Schankerman (1984), “The Rate of Obsolescence of Patents, Research Gestation Lags,
and the Private Rate of Return to Research Resources”, in Griliches, Z. (ed) “R&D, Patents, and
Productivity”, University of Chicago Press.
Popp, D., Santen, N., Fisher-Vanden, K., and M. Webster (2012), “Technology Variation vs. R&D
Uncertainty: What Matters Most for Energy Patent Success?” NBER Working Papers No. 17792,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., www.nber.org/papers/w17792 .
Régibeau, P. and K. Rockett (2010), “Innovation Cycles and Learning at the Patent Office: Does the Early
Patent Get the Delay?”, The Journal of Industrial Economics, 58 (2): 222-246.
Scherer, F. M. (1965). “Firm Size, Market Structure, Opportunity, and the Output of Patented Inventions”,
American Economic Review, 55(5): 1097-1125.
Schmoch, U. (2008), “Concept of a Technology Classification for Country Comparisons”, Final Report to
the World Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO), revised August 2011, WIPO,
www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/ipstats/en/statistics/patents/pdf/wipo_ipc_technology.pdf
(last
accessed 30 October 2012).
Shane, S. (2001), “Technological Opportunities and New Firm Creation”, Management Science, 47 (2):
205–220.
Srivastava, M. K., and D. R. Gnyawali (2011). “When Do Relational Resources Matter? Leveraging
Portfolio Technological Resources for Breakthrough Innovation”. Academy of Management Journal,
54(4): 797-810.
Svensson, R. (2012), “Commercialization, renewal, and quality of patents”, Economics of Innovation and
New Technology, 21(2): 175-201.
Stahl, J. C. (2010). “Mergers and Sequential Innovation: Evidence from Patent Citations”. Finance and
Economics Discussion Series, No. 2010-12. Division of Research and Statistics and Monetary
Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC.
Tong, X and J. Davidson (1994), “Measuring national technological performance with patent claims data”,
Research Policy, 23: 133-141.
Trajtenberg, M. (1990), “A Penny for Your Quotes: Patent Citations and the Value of Innovation”, RAND
Journal of Economics, 21 (1): 172-187.
Trajtenberg, M, Jaffe, A., and R. Henderson (1997). “University versus Corporate Patents: A Window on
the Basicness of Inventions”, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 5(1): 19-50.
Webb, C., H. Dernis, D. Harhoff and K. Hoisl (2005), “Analysing European and International Patent
Citations: A Set of EPO Patent Database Building Blocks”, OECD Science, Technology and
Industry Working Papers, No. 2005/9, OECD, Paris.
World
Intellectual Property Organization
www.wipo.int/classifications/ipc/en/
(WIPO).
(last
International
accessed
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
Patent
30
Classification (IPC).
October
2012).
127 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
CHAPTER 3. APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
This chapter takes stock of the protection of trade secrets in a sample of economies, taking into
account the legal framework in each, including the scope, coverage and remedies available. To
facilitate the stocktaking, the chapter develops an indicator of the stringency of trade secrets
protection. The chapter therefore provides information and tools that are necessary to set up the
following chapter, which uses the indicator to assess the economic performance implications of
variations in the stringency of protection, with both qualitative and quantitative methods.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities or third
party. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and
Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
It should be noted that statistical data on Israeli patents and trademarks are supplied by the patent and trademark
offices of the relevant countries.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
128 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
ABSTRACT
This chapter takes stock of the available legal protection for trade secrets (undisclosed information) in
a broad initial sample of countries. Drawing on national and international material, the chapter develops
and presents an indicator of the stringency of protection of trade secrets (the Trade Secrets Protection
Index) and provides an assessment of variation in the available protection. The result is a finding that while
the sample countries have some similarities, notably with respect to definition and scope of trade secrets,
they have many more substantial dissimilarities with respect to implementation of protection for trade
secrets. For example, differences are particularly pronounced in evidence gathering and discovery,
protection of trade secrets during litigation, technology transfer requirements and the effectiveness of legal
systems with respect to enforcement. This diversity is reflected in the wide range of scores in the Trade
Secrets Protection Index. Such variation in the stringency of protection for trade secrets may influence
firm-level decision-making and may have implications for some aspects of economic performance (in
particular, in relation to innovation).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
129 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
This background chapter takes stock of the available legal protection for trade secrets (undisclosed
information) and presents a method for the assessment of the stringency of available protection. The
objective is to better understand the nature of the protection and how it might vary across a broad initial
sample of countries. This information will provide an essential input for the second phase of the project
that considers the relationship of the stringency of trade secrets protection to relevant aspects of economic
performance (Chapter 4).
The chapter prepares the foundation for the work by defining trade secrets and presenting the
international framework. Trade secrets are defined, essentially, as concerning information that is secret,
that has commercial value because of its status as secret, and that is the subject of reasonable efforts to
protect the secrecy. This definition is in line with the approach presented in the World Trade
Organization’s Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, the first multilateral
agreement to require protection for trade secrets. The chapter then moves to consider the current economic
and legal literature, which is fairly substantial in terms of legal scholarship but less complete with respect
to economic analysis.
Using a structured comparative approach, the chapter examines national legal regimes for a diverse
sample of countries (including the BRICS, five other partner countries and 11 OECD countries). Drawing
on national and international material, the chapter develops and presents an indicator of the stringency of
protection of trade secrets (the Trade Secrets Protection Index). The chapter provides a taxonomy of
elements of protection for trade secrets, text tables describing the main characteristics of the regimes in the
sample countries, and detailed narrative overviews for the trade secrets legal regimes in the BRICS and
OECD countries in the sample.
The result of this assessment is a finding that while the sample countries have some similarities,
notably with respect to definition and scope of trade secrets, they have many more substantial
dissimilarities with respect to implementation of protection for trade secrets. For example, differences are
particularly pronounced in evidence gathering and discovery, protection of trade secrets during litigation,
technology transfer requirements and the effectiveness of legal systems with respect to enforcement,
among other differences. This diversity is reflected in the wide range of scores in the preliminary Trade
Secrets Protection Index. Such variation in the stringency of protection for trade secrets may influence
firm-level decision-making and may have implications for some aspects of economic performance (in
particular, in relation to innovation).
The next chapter expands the sample and focuses on economic analysis. It is based on dual
approaches: a qualitative assessment and a quantitative assessment. Its objective is to examine empirically
the relationship between the stringency of protection for trade secrets and performance concerning the
types of economic indicators that may be hypothesised to be responsive to variation in protection of trade
secrets. Such an assessment may help policy-makers in the identification of policy options for improved
economic performance with respect to trade secrets.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
130 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Introduction
This background chapter takes stock of the available legal protection for trade secrets and presents a
method for the assessment of the stringency of available protection. The objective is to better understand
the nature of the protection and how it might vary across a broad initial sample of countries. This
information will provide an essential input for the second phase of the project that will consider the
relationship of the stringency of trade secrets protection to relevant aspects of economic performance.
The present chapter is structured around an introduction, five substantive sections, and a conclusion.
In section 2, the chapter prepares the foundation for the work by defining trade secrets and presenting the
international framework. It then moves to consider the current legal and economic literature. The following
section presents an overview of the method employed in the analysis. Using a comparative approach, the
fifth section of the chapter examines national legal regimes for the initial sample of countries. Drawing on
the national and international material, the chapter proposes a set of elements for inclusion in an indicator
of the stringency of protection of trade secrets. The subsequent section presents an implementation of this
method for the sample countries. The conclusions provide some observations on the results and next
steps 85.
The work has employed a sampling approach in order to gauge the variation in available trade secret
protection. The sample of countries is structured to capture diversity in terms of: (1) approaches to
protection of trade secrets (i.e. in terms of civil, criminal and common law), (2) geography (e.g. country
location, size and endowments), (3) income level (upper middle and high income countries) and (4)
country grouping (i.e. OECD or partner status). A further constraint was availability of data needed to
conduct the research. The resulting sample covers the BRICS and five other partner countries plus a
sample of 11 OECD countries, including: Australia, Brazil, Bulgaria, the People’s Republic of China,
Colombia, France, Germany, India, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, New Zealand, Peru, Russian
Federation, Singapore, South Africa, Sweden, United Kingdom and United States. The chapter focuses on
the situation in these countries for the most recent period available, generally 2010.
The International Framework and the Definition of Trade Secrets
The countries in the sample are all members of the World Trade Organization (WTO) and are subject
to the provisions of the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS). The
TRIPS Agreement was the first international agreement to protect trade secrets expressly (Box 3.1.). The
approach laid out in the TRIPS Agreement is based on the notion that protection against unfair competition
should include protection for undisclosed information. In presenting this approach, the TRIPS Agreement
makes reference to the prior-existing protection against unfair competition as presented in the Paris
Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property (Box 3.2.), a convention that is administered by the
World Intellectual Property Organization.
Although trade secrets are confidential, they are also commercial. For a trade secret to have any
practical value, the owner usually must share it in order to collaborate with a limited group of employees
and business partners. Laws thus expect and account for a certain amount of protected disclosure, within a
constrained circle. Nevertheless, even if trade secrets are not “secret” in the strictest sense of the term, they
must in fact remain non-public and known only to a limited number of people. The definition of trade
secrets thus is broadly similar among countries, addressing their dual nature as confidential but
commercial.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
131 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Box 3.1. The TRIPS Agreement on Undisclosed Information
Protection of undisclosed information is addressed in Article 39 of the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of
Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) of the World Trade Organization (WTO). This agreement entered into force on
1 January 1995 and established an international standard requiring WTO Members to protect undisclosed information
including agricultural and pharmaceutical test data.
Section 7: Protection of Undisclosed Information, Article 39
1. In the course of ensuring effective protection against unfair competition as provided in Article 10bis of the Paris
Convention (1967), Members shall protect undisclosed information in accordance with paragraph 2 and data submitted
86
to governments or governmental agencies in accordance with paragraph 3 .
2. Natural and legal persons shall have the possibility of preventing information lawfully within their control from
being disclosed to, acquired by, or used by others without their consent in a manner contrary to honest commercial
87
practices so long as such information:
(a) is secret in the sense that it is not, as a body or in the precise configuration and assembly of its
components, generally known among or readily accessible to persons within the circles that normally deal with
the kind of information in question;
(b)
has commercial value because it is secret; and
(c) has been subject to reasonable steps under the circumstances, by the person lawfully in control of the
information, to keep it secret.
3. Members, when requiring, as a condition of approving the marketing of pharmaceutical or of agricultural
chemical products which utilise new chemical entities, the submission of undisclosed test or other data, the origination
of which involves a considerable effort, shall protect such data against unfair commercial use. In addition, Members
shall protect such data against disclosure, except where necessary to protect the public, or unless steps are taken to
ensure that the data are protected against unfair commercial use.
Source: Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS), WTO.
The similarities among countries in defining trade secrets correspond well with the three requirements
of Article 39 of TRIPS. In fact, on this matter, TRIPS reflected then-current practice in many countries and
it has shaped subsequent law-making. In practice, the TRIPS requirements for trade secrets are now
generally applied in law as follows:
•
Secrecy. The information protected must actually be secret. Secrecy need not be absolute. The
trade secret owner may share the information with employees and business partners. Secrecy
requires instead that the information must not be readily publically accessible and that it is
revealed to others only under conditions that maintain secrecy with respect to the broader
public 88.
•
Commercial Value. The information must have economic value as a result of its being secret.
Trade secret law most typically protects commercial information; that information must derive
some utility from being kept secret.
•
Reasonable Efforts to Maintain Secrecy. The information must be the subject of reasonable
efforts on the part of the rights holder to maintain its secrecy. By its nature, a trade secret claim
arises when measures to protect the secret have failed. Thus, the law does not require one who
claims a trade secret to be entirely successful at protecting it. However, the law does require the
owner to make some efforts to maintain secrecy. In national laws, the necessary effort is often
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
132 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
broadly described as “reasonable,” in keeping with Article 39 of TRIPS. However, some
countries impose more specific, additional obligations, which might be characterised as a
particular implementation of the broad reasonableness requirement. For example, some common
law countries require that the defendant have a contractual or implied obligation to keep the
information secret. Other countries require written agreements with recipients and confidentiality
notices.
These three conditions define trade secrets in a manner covering a potentially very large scope of
economic activity 89. Still, the resulting definition has potentially important practical implications as
pointed out by Maskus (2000), who notes that trade secrets “are not protected against learning by fair
means, such as independent creation, reverse engineering or reading public documents.” In other words,
trade secrecy does not provide an exclusive right to use of the information, so long as a second party
obtains the information fairly or it enters the public domain by fair means. Thus, unlike patented inventions
or copyright protected content, trade secrets are not protected for a statutory time limit and they can run out
in the regular course of competition. The range of subject matter covered by trade secrets may be openended, though often trade secrets fall into one of two broad categories: technical information (e.g. technical
plans and formulae) and confidential business information (e.g. customer lists and marketing strategies)
(Almeling et al., 2010).
The TRIPS Agreement requires that WTO members put in place national systems to protect trade
secrets against acts of unfair competition (Sandeen, 2011). WTO members comply with this obligation in a
variety of ways. The fact that TRIPS Article 39 does not set forth a detailed regime for protection is
associated with substantial variation between countries in the means employed to provide the TRIPS mandated protection. In some instances, countries have implemented express legislation. In others, the
obligation is met by laws that include misappropriation via such means as breach of contract, inducement
of others to breach contracts and acquisition by third parties of information known to be disclosed
dishonestly (or where it was negligent not to know). This variation can affect the ways businesses and
workers conduct their affairs and thus there are reasons to believe that the legal protection of trade secrets
may have important economic effects.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
133 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Box 3.2. Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property, Articles 1 and 10bis, 1967 90
In protecting Trade Secrets, the TRIPS Agreement references the protection provided in the Paris
Convention against unfair competition. Article 10bis of the Paris Convention highlights the nature of
protection against unfair competition. Article 1 of the Paris Convention is included here to provide context
concerning what is meant by “union” (see article 1.1). Article 1 also defines the scope of industrial property
originally covered, which the TRIPS Agreement extends by explicitly providing for protection of undisclosed
information.
Selected articles of the Paris Convention
Article 1: Establishment of the Union; Scope of Industrial Property
(1) The countries to which this Convention applies constitute a Union for the protection of industrial
property.
(2) The protection of industrial property has as its object patents, utility models, industrial designs,
trademarks, service marks, trade names, indications of source or appellations of origin, and the repression of
unfair competition.
(3) Industrial property shall be understood in the broadest sense and shall apply not only to industry
and commerce proper, but likewise to agricultural and extractive industries and to all manufactured or natural
products, for example, wines, grain, tobacco leaf, fruit, cattle, minerals, mineral waters, beer, flowers, and
flour.
(4) Patents shall include the various kinds of industrial patents recognised by the laws of the countries
of the Union, such as patents of importation, patents of improvement, patents and certificates of addition, etc.
Article 10bis: Unfair Competition
(1) The countries of the Union are bound to assure to nationals of such countries effective protection
against unfair competition.
(2) Any act of competition contrary to honest practices in industrial or commercial matters constitutes
an act of unfair competition.
(3)
The following in particular shall be prohibited:
(i) all acts of such a nature as to create confusion by any means whatever with the establishment, the
goods, or the industrial or commercial activities, of a competitor;
(ii) false allegations in the course of trade of such a nature as to discredit the establishment, the goods,
or the industrial or commercial activities, of a competitor;
(iii) indications or allegations the use of which in the course of trade is liable to mislead the public as to
the nature, the manufacturing process, the characteristics, the suitability for their purpose, or the quantity, of
the goods.
Source: World Intellectual Property Organization.
Literature Review
The legal and economic literature on trade secrets is relatively limited in quantity and scope compared
to the literature regarding other forms of intellectual property. The portions most relevant to this chapter
fall into two categories: i) conceptual theories of trade secret law and ii) economic assessments regarding
the effects of trade secret law.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
134 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
The Conceptual Debate Regarding Trade Secret Law
There is a robust debate in the legal literature as to whether trade secret law is based on relational
obligations (for example, contract, employment status, or fiduciary duty); property rights; fairness and
equity; or unfair competition law tort or delict. A fifth position offered by Bone (1998) and characterised
by Claeys (2011) as “trade secrecy nihilism” contends that trade secret law lacks any unified theory, but is
rather a collection of approaches and norms regarding the protection of business information. Claeys
(2011) and Risch (2007) survey this debate in the context of current US law, Richardson et al., (2012)
examine the historical evolution and debate among various conceptions in the law of the England and other
common law jurisdictions, while Knobel (2000) provides an example of the debate in the context of South
African law, where trade secret protection is based on the ancient Roman Lex Aquilia. Views of the basis
for trade secret protection vary both within and between countries. For example, Claeys (2011), in contrast
to Bone (1998), contends that the proprietary account does the best job of explaining the structure of trade
secret protection in the United States, including rights and remedies. By contrast, Gurry (2012) explains
that under English law trade secrets are protected by an action for breach of confidence under a
relationship-based view of trade secrecy.
The differing conceptions of trade secret law result from different normative and conceptual premises.
The US Supreme Court observed, citing John Locke and Blackstone, that the “perception of trade secrets
as property is consonant with a notion of ‘property’ that extends beyond land and tangible goods and
includes the products of an individual's ‘labour and invention.’”91 The Court further observed that “[t]rade
secrets have many of the characteristics of more tangible forms of property” 92; in particular, the Court
noted that they are alienable in various ways, which is a hallmark of property rights. Some scholars
contend that trade secrets cannot be property because they do not provide exclusive rights against the
world (Bone, 1998). However, Claeys describes trade secrets as simply a different form of property right,
like water rights rather than rights in land (Claeys, 2013). In this conception, they are usufructory rights,
which confer rights to use a resource and to be free from interference with use, but which do not confer the
right to exclude those who derive benefits from the resource by their independent efforts. By contrast,
some jurisdictions ground trade secret rights in duties between the parties. Thus, for example, UK trade
secrecy law sanctions breaches of confidence where the information was imparted in confidence, thus
giving rise to a duty (Gurry, 2012).
The answer to this debate regarding the conceptual basis for trade secret law can be consequential. For
example, the US Supreme Court’s conclusion that trade secrets are protected as property had the
implication that the US Government’s forcing of disclosure of such information may require compensation
under the US Constitution. Whereas, most European countries do not conceive of trade secrets as property
and, therefore, they are not subject to the EU Enforcement Directive, which is also significant. The
Enforcement Directive provides for certain procedures and remedies that facilitate the investigation and
pursuit of intellectual property claims, for example.
Economics and Trade Secret Law
Incentives
The economic literature describes the economic justification for trade secret law in terms of the
incentives it provides. It describes three types of incentives. First, it provides incentives to invent and to
invest in the development of valuable business information. Second, it relieves businesses of the need to
invest in some costly measures to prevent breach of security. Third, it encourages businesses to engage in
wider (albeit limited) dissemination of information than they otherwise would, thus increasing the
likelihood of knowledge spillovers. Given the importance of trade secrets in many economies (Box 3.3.),
the potential impacts of such incentives would appear to be significant.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
135 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
A number of studies indicate that protection of trade secrets can encourage the development of
inventions and valuable information by helping to secure the return on the investment in creating such
innovations. Kitch (1980) characterises the incentive in terms of risk reduction: trade secrets are
particularly at risk from theft because they have a low rate of depreciation. Friedman et al. (1991) similarly
view the incentive effect as increasing the return to research and development by lowering the cost of
protection. Others see the incentive function as similar to patents, where trade secrets essentially serve as a
substitute for patents where the latter are unavailable or too expensive. Maskus (2000) and Friedman et al.
(1991) argue that that trade secrets can substitute for patents and provide incentives to innovate, where:
1) an invention is unpatentable, but hard to imitate, such that there is value in keeping the information
confidential (e.g. a customer list), 2) a firm may prefer to avoid the public disclosure required by a patent,
and 3) where a firm may wish to avoid the cost of obtaining a patent. Still others see the incentive-to-invest
arising from competitive effects. Lemley (2011) observes that protection of trade secrets can help
innovators to maintain a competitive advantage such as might be obtained via a unique process of
production or product; this can contribute to profitability and thereby provides incentives for further
investment in innovation.
Some scholars critique the incentive-to-invest account. Risch (2007 and 2011) points out that trade
secrets can only protect information that firms already can, and do, keep secret. They thus create no new
ability to keep information secret. He argues that firms already have an incentive to invest in creating
secret information. In this view, trade secret protection has a relatively small marginal effect on investment
in research and development. They serve to assure firms that they may be able to secure an injunction to
“rescue” a secret that that is threatened, stolen, or disclosed, or to secure damages. Bone (1998) also
critiques the incentive-to-invest theory as overestimating benefits and underestimating the cost of keeping
secrets.
Other studies point to a second justification for trade secrets, noting that the provision of adequate
legal protection reduces the need to invest in inefficient and costly protection for trade secrets beyond the
requirements of the law. As Friedman et al. (1991) observe, the availability of trade secret protection
discourages use of less efficient alternative approaches to protection (e.g. hiring only family members or
paying wage premia to prevent employee movement) and also inefficient activity by competitors to
discover trade secrets (e.g. bribery or espionage). As Risch (2007) points out, both trade secret owners and
competitors are channelled into more efficient behaviour. The owner optimises, rather than maximises,
security. The competitor spends less money in attempting to appropriate the secret.
A third justification for trade secrets found in the literature relates, somewhat ironically, to their
effects in encouraging knowledge dissemination, at least as compared to absolute secrecy. As Lemley
(2011) argues, trade secret protection enlarges the circle of people to whom it is safe to reveal information.
Thus employees who may eventually depart are more likely to have the opportunity to learn from the trade
secret. Even if they do not misappropriate the original secret, they may benefit from their enhanced stock
of knowledge, as may future employers. Risch (2007) also contends that the incentives to rely on legal
rather than physical means to guard secrets encourage owners to employ lesser levels of protection, thus
increasing the likelihood of “leakage,” and subsequently knowledge dissemination. In a further study, Png
(2012a) found that some US states enacting increased trade secret protection may have experienced
relatively modest declines in the mobility of postgraduate engineers and scientists (e.g. due to enforcement
of contractual requirements concerning non-competition); this in turn might slow the pace spillover effects.
However, this effect might be mitigated depending on presumptions states make related to possible
disclosures (e.g. depending on whether they apply a doctrine of “inevitable disclosure”). Moreover, the
possible costs to innovation due to any reduction in spillovers from reduced mobility of these
most-qualified personnel may be off-set to some extent by the benefits to innovation from increased
incentives to invest in R&D.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
136 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Box 3.3. References to the Economic Importance of Trade Secrets
While the secrecy requirements make it difficult to estimate the economic value of trade secrets, some indications
are available from the literature 93. Some estimates for the United States in the past decade, for example, put the
annual cost of trade secret theft to US firms as high as USD 300 billion (Almeling et al., 2010). In a further example,
interviews with members of the European Chemical Industry Council revealed that misappropriation of a trade secret
or confidential business information could often entail a loss of revenue for a firm of up to 30% and sometimes much
more (CEFIC, 2012). Clearly, businesses suffer when trade secrets are compromised. They risk potential losses to
reputation, image, goodwill, competitive advantage, core technology and profitability (ASIS, 2007; Hogan Lovells,
2010; USTR, 2012).
This point is underscored in a recent EC-sponsored survey of 537 businesses in Europe (EC, 2013). Among
survey respondents, 75% ranked trade secrets as “strategically important to their company’s growth, competitiveness
and innovative performance.” This reliance on trade secrets applied to firms of all sizes including small and medium
size enterprises. The main reason cited by business (52%) for use of trade secrets over other forms of intellectual
property protection was to avoid public disclosure of valuable information. In many countries, the relative ease of use
and lack of registration requirements for trade secrets have led innovative small and medium size enterprises to rely on
trade secrets as the default mode of intellectual property protection (Brant and Lohse, 2013). Moreover, unlike
copyright or patent protection, trade secret law is not a particularly technical body of law.
The growing importance of trade secrets is underscored by recent government initiatives to improve protection.
For example, in 2012, the European Commission released an indicative roadmap for an initiative to improve protection
of trade secrets and confidential business information from misappropriation and misuse by third parties 94. In 2013, the
United States released the “Administration Strategy on Mitigating the Theft of US Trade Secrets”, which included a set
of action items for improved protection domestically and internationally 95.
Patent Versus Trade Secrets Protection
There is an extensive body of literature on the trade-offs between patents and trade secrets at both the
institutional and firm level. Pooley (1997, 2012 update, pp. 32-40), for example, offers advice to firms
wishing to protect their intellectual assets in which he highlights differences in protection between patents
and trade secrets. He notes that often the nature of the asset provides a clear indication of the appropriate
protection. Patents generally offer protection for specific technological inventions that are useful, novel
and non-obvious. The patent process can be time consuming and expensive, requiring public disclosure of
the idea. But, within the bounds of strictly defined claims, once a patent is issued, it offers the prospect of
market exclusivity for a specific period. Trade secret protection is generally available for a broad range of
commercial information that is useful and not widely known, but need not be novel. The broad scope
covers subject matter that may not be patentable such as know-how. Provided appropriate efforts are made
to ensure secrecy, trade secrets offer the possibility of protection without a limitation on duration, though
not against independent discovery by a competitor or inadvertent disclosure by the owner 96. Nonetheless,
in many instances the innovators seeking protection for an idea face a choice in the type of protection they
will seek.
The choice of protection can have social welfare implications. On the one hand, as Friedman et al.
(1991) point out, patents offer the social welfare advantage of encouraging disclosure with all the positive
spillover effects that may result. On the other hand, Cugno and Ottoz (2006) offer a model where trade
secrecy is more socially optimal, because of the independent invention defence, which exists at all times
with respect to a trade secret, but is either limited or non-existent in patent law 97. As a result, trade secret
owners may have fewer opportunities to charge supra-competitive prices.
The empirical literature shows that firms tend to rely heavily on trade secrets. Arundel (2001) found
that European firms tended to prefer trade secrets to patents, with the preference more pronounced among
smaller firms. Cohen et al. (2000) found similar results in a survey of US firms. An econometric study by
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
137 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Png (2012b) exploited variation among the laws of the US states and included construction of a simple
index of trade secret protection. He found that between 1976 and 2006 US states that enacted trade secrets
laws tended to experience increases in research and development expenditure (R&D) by high-tech and
large manufacturing firms. At the same time, there was a tendency among such firms to reduce their
reliance on patenting. Maskus (2012, p. 237) points out that trade secrets, in principle, can play an
important role in developing countries where they offer a readily available form of protection for
incremental innovation for which patents may not be available, financially viable or profit maximising.
Method
In order to pursue the economic analysis in the next phase of the present project, an indicator for the
stringency of trade secrets protection is needed. The availability of such an indicator will permit
comparisons of the stringency of trade secrets protection against relevant aspects of economic performance
while controlling for other conditions. The strategy employed here is to take stock of the broad range of
elements of legal protection for trade secrets, to consolidate this inventory into a list of elements that
captures the key features of protection and that can generally be determined empirically, and then to
compile an index based on these elements grouped into distinct components each representing a key aspect
of protection. Rather than developing multiple indicators, a single index can offer the opportunity for
various levels of analysis. The combined index score can be considered when an indicator of overall
protection is appropriate or the index can be disaggregated into the key components for consideration of
specific aspects of protection of trade secrets.
The analysis considers two sets of “elements” in order to gauge the variation in the available trade
secrets protection and develop an index as a tool for use in the subsequent economic analysis. First, in
order to determine the basic legal framework, the authors examined laws on the books and key cases that
directly or indirectly relate to trade secret protection. This was done using the original laws, standard legal
references and related expert commentary. Secondly, the functioning of the legal system was considered in
relation to enforcement of trade secret protection in practice and in relation to alternative protection
strategies. This was done via consideration of existing international indicators (e.g. available from World
Economic Forum or Fraser Institute, among others), the academic literature, standard legal references and
related expert commentary 98.
The research design for this project presented a preliminary list of candidates for each of the two sets
of elements. The elements were chosen for three reasons: (1) the presence or absence of these elements
could allow one to make meaningful statements about the stringency of rights with respect to trade secrets;
(2) they could represent significant differences among the laws of various countries; and (3) they may
plausibly have marginal effects on the costs faced by firms (e.g. with respect to necessary secrecy
measures) or their innovation-related decisions (e.g. regarding foreign direct investment (FDI) or resources
devoted to research). Certain of these elements are referenced in the TRIPS Agreement, such as the
protection of undisclosed pharmaceutical or agricultural chemical test data submitted in relation to
marketing approval (Article 39.3) 99. However, it is not within the scope of this chapter to draw any specific
assessment with respect to the TRIPS Agreement.
In implementing the research design, the preliminary list of elements was refined through an
interactive process taking account of findings from our examination of the sample countries. The priority
objective in this was to ensure coverage of key elements of the system of protection of trade secrets. Some
new elements were added in this regard (e.g. with respect to availability of injunctions to eliminate
wrongful head starts) and others were refined (e.g. the element for availability of emergency search to
preserve and obtain proof was refined to take into account whether ex parte searches are available and who
does them). Once coverage of key elements was ensured, a further consolidation of the elements was
undertaken to avoid redundancy in the final set, to give particular focus to dimensions where there is
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
138 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
variability between countries, and to ensure that internationally comparable information on the selected
elements could be obtained via reasonable research efforts.
The research design takes the various legal means for protecting trade secrets and abstracts and
generalises them into a set of common, comparable elements. The resulting elements are still recognisable,
meaningful and useful descriptions of legal provisions, but they are no longer bound to the context of a
particular legal system. When the researchers examined a country’s laws, they identified and isolated these
elements regardless of labels – any law that directly 100 addresses trade secrets is covered, regardless of
whether it explicitly mentions “trade secrets” or undisclosed information and whether it exclusively
addresses trade secrets (in many cases, labour laws, tort laws, unfair competition laws, criminal codes, and
procedural codes were all relevant). The research also identified these elements without regard to where
they were found – it examined all legal methods for protecting trade secrets, such as statutory law,
common law, administrative remedies, and laws of general application. The key consideration was
identifying an objective indication of whether the element existed in a country’s laws and how it was
implemented.
The methodology employed here allows for effective cross-country comparisons despite considerable
differences among legal systems. As a long-standing tradition of comparative law scholarship recognises, it
is possible to readily and clearly identify common points of law between countries despite very different
legal systems 101,102. The next section of this chapter surveys the situation for each country in the sample on
the basis of the refined list of elements and considers similarities and points of divergence across the
sample.
Survey of Legal Provisions and Practices
The results of the survey of legal provisions and practices are documented in Annex 1: Country
Charts and Preliminary Index Scoring (Schultz & Lippoldt, 2014). The Annex presents results with respect
to: source of law, definition and scope; covered acts; definition of duties and misappropriation; restrictions
on liability; remedies; enforcement, investigation and discovery, and related regulations; and expert
characterisation of the operation of the system in practice.
The survey of legal provisions confirms that there is great variation among approaches to trade secret
protection. The laws of various countries are harmonised at a high level of generality only. The following
discussion briefly surveys similarities and differences among the trade secret laws of various countries.
Similarities among Countries
As discussed in the Introduction, countries have similar definitions of trade secrecy due to the nature
of trade secrets and the requirements of TRIPS. Beyond the similarities to the broad, three-part definition
set forth in Article 39 of TRIPS, however, there are several other points of similarity among the trade
secret laws of the countries surveyed in this chapter.
•
Scope. The scope of trade secret protection, while not the same in every country, follows
certain well-defined categories. These categories are (1) technical information; (2)
confidential business information; and (3) know-how. Technical information typically
includes industrial processes, blueprints, formulae, and similar information regarding
technology. Confidential business information typically includes customer lists (at least
to the extent they include truly non-public information), financial information, business
plans and similar information regarding the operation of a business. Know-how includes
information about methods, steps and processes for achieving efficient results. Most
countries recognise the first two categories (although they often treat them the same).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
139 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Know-how is a term commonly used both in discussion of proprietary information and
in agreements, but enjoys less formal recognition as a separate, defined category of trade
secrets.
•
Defences. Independent creation of a trade secret, where the defendant created a trade
secret without access or reference to the plaintiff’s trade secret, is explicitly or implicitly
a universally recognised defence. Reverse engineering is also widely explicitly
recognised as permissible and likely to be permissible in almost all cases.
•
Third Party Liability. A third party that receives trade secrets with knowledge or reason
to know that they were provided in violation of trade secret law is typically liable. Third
parties that innocently and unknowingly receive trade secrets are less commonly liable,
but they are still subject to injunctions in some jurisdictions.
•
Remedies. Very broadly speaking, trade secret protection provides for civil remedies of
injunctions and damages. However, this category is as much a source of variation as
similarity and is thus discussed below. While the laws on the books provide for these
remedies, they vary widely in specifics and practical availability.
Key Points of Divergence
As foreshadowed above, the lack of a comprehensive international standard results in substantial
variation among the legal systems with respect to trade secrets. The points of divergence are more
numerous than the points of similarity. The following are key points of divergence among the laws of the
countries studied:
•
Civil vs. Criminal. A basic point of variation is whether a country protects trade secrets
primarily through civil law, criminal law, or both – or, in some cases, administrative
law.
•
Scope. The most commonly protected category of trade secret is technical information.
Most countries also protect confidential business information, and typically do not
distinguish it from technical information. This equal treatment of technical information
and confidential business information, however, does not necessarily prevail in every
country 103.
•
Duty. Systems vary in how duties are imposed. In some instances, trade secret
protection applies only where a defendant breaches a contractual or implied duty of
confidentiality. In other instances, in addition to cases of breach of duty, trade secret law
also applies where the secret was wrongfully obtained. In other instances, trade secrets
are protected as intellectual property rights (IPRs). In those cases, the owner simply has
exclusive rights to use them, without being required to show breach of duty or
misappropriation, subject to the rights of others to independently develop or reverse
engineer them.
•
Remedies. Remedies vary widely in details and practical availability. One reason for the
variance is that trade secret remedies tend to reflect national practice more than other
intellectual property remedies, which have often been harmonised because of various
international or transnational obligations, such as the European Union’s Enforcement
Directive. Thus, the types of damages available tend to depend largely on how the law
of a particular country defines and awards damages. The availability of injunctive relief
is partly a matter of national practice, but also a matter of the amount of proof required.
Remedies such as seizure and return of materials are also typically matters of national
law practice.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
140 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
•
Evidence Gathering and Discovery. Obtaining proof in trade secret cases is challenging.
By their very nature, trade secrets constitute information that is not readily ascertainable
and that can be hidden. Thus, evidence that a defendant has wrongfully obtained a trade
secret may be similarly non-public and hidden. Moreover, a defendant may wish to keep
trade secrets confidential for reasons other than legal liability – it too may wish to gain a
commercial advantage against all competitors other than the original owner.
For these reasons, proof of trade secret theft is often solely or largely in the possession of the
defendant and closely guarded. There is some danger that the defendant can effectively destroy such
evidence if it becomes aware of a lawsuit. It also may be necessary to conduct an in-depth investigation to
determine what was taken, how it was taken, by whom, and what has been done with it. These issues may
not be readily apparent from easily accessible sources. It thus may be difficult to build a case without
assembling documents, physical evidence, and conducting interviews.
Various references in the literature indicate that the ability to gather evidence in a trade secret case is
crucial. Yet, the approaches vary widely among countries. This variation is largely a matter of national
procedural law and practice in civil cases generally. On one end of the spectrum of discovery laws and
practice is the United States, with its very broad disclosure rules and practice. These rules and practices
make it easier to prove a case, but are often criticised as greatly increasing the expense and duration of
litigation. Toward the other end of the spectrum are many civil law countries, where pre-trial discovery is
limited, typically confined to documentary evidence, and done under the direct supervision of the court. At
the furthest end of the spectrum may be China, which has extremely limited discovery, but where,
according to experts, courts prefer original, documentary evidence to prove a case, which is very difficult
to obtain without extensive discovery.
Another point of variation in evidence gathering rules and practices is the availability of a
preliminary, emergency action to preserve proof. Many, but not all, countries have emergency, pre-trial
procedures to preserve evidence. In their broadest forms, these procedures (often called “Anton Piller”
orders after the English case from which many common law countries take their procedure) allow a party
to obtain ex parte approval to conduct a search of a prospective (i.e. before a case begins) defendant’s
premises and to seize relevant evidence.
Under the broadest form of this procedure, available in a limited number of countries, a plaintiff may
obtain a search on an ex parte basis and send a representative to direct the search. Plaintiffs in trade secret
cases value these features, as the lack of advance warning prevents a prospective defendant from
concealing evidence. Also, the presence of plaintiff’s representative at the search makes it much more
likely that the search finds relevant evidence because of the plaintiff’s expertise and detailed knowledge of
the trade secret. However, these features are not available in most countries surveyed. In fact, several
countries have no preliminary search procedure at all.
While the interest of a plaintiff in securing evidence may be key to many trade secret cases, several
jurisdictions have moved to balance plaintiffs’ needs against defendants’ rights. The experience of the
United Kingdom and other jurisdictions has raised concerns that a plaintiff may, ironically, use preliminary
procedures to misappropriate a defendant’s secrets or interfere with its business (Andrews, 1987). Thus,
authorities have clarified that courts should not grant such orders routinely. For example, the Chief Justice
of the Australian Federal Court issued “Federal Court Practice Note No. 24—Search Orders (also known
as “Anton Piller Orders”)” (5 May 2006) to curb perceived abuses of such orders.
•
Duty of Employees. Employees are typically, but not everywhere, under an implied duty of
confidentiality during the term of employment. Express agreements to keep information
confidential are enforceable during the term of employment. There is wide variation as to what an
employee’s duties are after termination of employment. Some jurisdictions will continue to
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
141 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
impose an implied duty after the end of employment, but many will not. Many restrict
enforcement of express contracts for confidentiality after employment as well. A typical
restriction on both express and implied duties is that they do not apply to general skills and
knowledge and cannot interfere with the employee’s ability to make a living.
•
Non-Compete Agreements. The enforceability of post-employment non-competition agreements
varies widely 104. Such is also the case with non-competition agreements between commercial
entities. Most typically, they are enforceable only if reasonable with respect to duration and
geographic scope. However, stricter regulation of enforceability, length, and scope is also the rule
in some countries. Non-compete agreements between commercial entities are also subject to
competition law. This chapter does not address competition regulation, as it does not appear to
affect trade secret protection uniquely, but rather applies to commercial agreements generally.
•
Protection of Secrets during Litigation. Trade secret litigation may expose the plaintiff’s
confidential information to security risks. First, the plaintiff needs to prove the existence of a
trade secret. The evidence submitted may expose the secret. Second, proving that the defendant
possesses the trade secret may require putting evidence on the record that further exposes the
secret. Finally, the court may need to discuss aspects of the secret in its orders and opinions.
Laws and procedures can mitigate these risks from litigation. A court may hold hearings “in
camera”—closed hearings open only to the parties, typically. The court may seal the record, thus blocking
public access to it. The court might also physically secure evidence, such as by locking it in a safe. It may
also restrict the access of the defendant and its personnel and agents to trade secrets (e.g., access might be
limited to the lawyers on the case). Finally, a court may redact portions of its published opinions or choose
not to publish the opinion at all.
From the commentary in the literature, it appears that the availability of these measures greatly affects
the risk in bringing a trade secret action. Without sufficient protection, a lawsuit could leave a plaintiff
worse off. A defendant may actually guard a trade secret, as it may confer an advantage over the
defendant’s and plaintiff’s mutual competitors. Thus, the prospect of a trade secret lawsuit in a country
with insecure court procedures could require a choice between not filing a suit and allowing a single
competitor to exploit one’s secret, and filing a suit and exposing the secret to all competitors.
Although litigation security measures appear important to effective trade secret protection, there is
wide variation in the availability and effectiveness of such measures among countries. Some countries
routinely provide in camera hearings, while others do not. There is also variation with respect to whether
defendant and all of its agents have full access to the record.
•
Data Exclusivity. Data exclusivity is a form of protection related to trade secret law. Data
exclusivity provisions govern the use of data submitted for regulatory approval of chemicals –
particularly pharmaceuticals and agricultural chemicals. There is a wide variance among
countries in how they implement these regimes. Most countries reviewed in this chapter protect
test data for new chemical entities from disclosure or from use by competitors seeking regulatory
approval for their own products for a term of years after regulatory approval 105. Some countries
also protect data submitted to obtain approval for new uses (as opposed to entirely new products),
but many do not.
•
Technology Transfer Regulations. In the 1960s and 1970s, many countries adopted technology
transfer laws regulating inbound technology licenses 106. These laws were intended to ensure that
foreign investors transferred know how to local enterprises and workers. They typically required
registration of agreements and often gave regulatory agencies the power to disapprove
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
142 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
substantive terms that interfered with technology transfer. Such provisions often affected trade
secrets. For example, some provisions prohibited indefinite length confidentiality provisions.
Others prohibited provisions that restricted the use of trade secrets after the expiration of the
agreement or that required return of materials containing trade secrets.
This review highlights a number of fields of law as they relate to trade secrets protection. From this, it
appears that general legal system quality may be particularly relevant in the case of trade secret protection
across the countries surveyed. Although the quality of the legal systems varies widely between countries, it
is a characteristic that plays an important role in trade secret protection. First, protection of trade secrets is
often put into practice through generally applicable causes of action such as contract enforcement, labour
law or tort actions. Reliable enforcement of contracts and property rights and the impartiality of the courts
are thus important to a trade secret regime. Second, trade secret owners are particularly dependent on
recourse to courts in the event of an appropriation because of the great vulnerability of trade secrets. Once
widely disclosed, they are extinguished. Thus, a prospective developer or owner of a trade secret must be
cognizant of how swift, reliable and predictable the courts are in case its own attempts to maintain secrecy
are breached.
A Deeper Look at Countries in the Survey
The foregoing comparison based on the Annex 1 charts highlights the substantial diversity among the
survey countries. In order to consider the origins of this diversity and its impact on the operations of the
legal systems for protection of trade secrets, a more detailed examination is carried out for the BRICS and
OECD countries. This is presented in Annex 2: Detailed Overviews for the BRICS and a Sample of OECD
Countries (Schultz & Lippoldt, 2014). The narrative discussions in Annex 2 serve to give a rich and full
sense of the issues that trade secret protection addresses and the common and diverse ways in which
countries address them.
Based on the international comparisons in Annex 2, a hierarchy of trade secret challenges
emerges which might be characterised as follows:
•
“Ordinary” Trade Secret Appropriation. These problems result from departing employees or
business partners taking information or from opportunistic competitors seizing an opportunity to
illicitly obtain information.
•
Corporate Espionage. These problems result from more systematic schemes by competitors to
infiltrate a competitor’s operations through such actions as planting employees, bribery or
extensive infiltration of computer systems or electronic eavesdropping.
•
State Sponsored Corporate Espionage. Increasingly, some governments are expressing grave
concerns regarding government-sponsored systematic schemes to appropriate trade secrets.
Ordinary trade secret appropriation is typically addressed through civil enforcement. Evidence of the
wrong is often in the possession of the trade secret owner or relatively easy to obtain. The laws of the
countries surveyed all address the problem of departing employees and other parties who appropriate trade
secrets by breaching contracts or other duties. This issue is typically addressed through a variety of means
– trade secret law, breach of contract, and/or labour law. There is greater divergence in addressing the
opportunistic behaviour of parties who do not have a prior relationship with the trade secret owner. Most
typically, the law addresses such actions as misappropriation. Not all countries recognise an action for
misappropriation. For example, common law jurisdictions take a relationship-based view of trade secrecy,
and thus some, for example New Zealand and India, do not recognise a civil action for misappropriation.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
143 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
The challenge of corporate espionage highlights the importance of criminal law for addressing
difficult problems of gathering evidence. A much smaller number of countries in the sample offer criminal
remedies. As the narratives show, where available, criminal law offers useful investigative tools against
systematic espionage such as “sting” operations and large-scale, long-term operations that are beyond the
means and authority of individual trade secret owners. In some jurisdictions, such as Germany, criminal
remedies play an important role in supplementing the limited discovery available in civil cases.
Another point that emerges from the narratives in Annex 2 is that the stringency of trade secret
protection in countries with relatively well-developed statutory protections can be undermined by specific
requirements and implementation factors. For example, China and Russia have fairly well-defined legal
protections, but the stringency of those protections is partly offset by weaknesses in implementation and
additional, unusual evidentiary requirements. In other countries, including Brazil, stringency of the laws on
the books is sometimes inconsistent with the approaches used in specific areas such as technology transfer
or data exclusivity.
Trade Secret Protection Index
From the foregoing discussion, it is clear that there is significant variation in the available protection
for trade secrets across this initial sample of countries. The next phase of this work, presented in Chapter 4,
expands the sample and considers the relevance of such variation for certain aspects of economic
performance, particularly those related to innovation. As noted above, in order to conduct a quantitative
assessment of the relationship, it is useful to have an indicator for the stringency of available trade secrets
protection. This section presents a preliminary version of an indicator developed for this purpose: the
Trade Secrets Protection Index (TSPI).
The development of the TSPI proceeded based on several considerations. First, five components were
designated as representing key aspects of protection of trade secrets that also emphasise features where
there is some variation across countries that may influence the stringency of protection. Second, the
relevant entries from the refined list of elements (i.e. from Annex 1) were grouped under the appropriate
component heading. The elements were phrased to enable scoring based primarily on objective criteria,
supplemented in some cases by qualitative information as necessary (e.g. in certain areas related to system
operation). Third, in order to ensure coherence across the components, the authors opted for an integrated
index approach rather than multiple indicators. (The TSPI can be disaggregated into its components if a
focus on certain aspects is helpful for a particular discussion.) Fourth, the index was designed to emphasise
transparency with scores supported by a text chart for each country and verifiable references. Fifth, the
index is designed to provide an indication of the stringency of available protection; it aims to be neutral in
this assessment. In other words, a higher or low score reflects the strength of protection and not an
assessment of the appropriate level of protection.
It bears emphasis that the index’s function is descriptive, not normative, and the scores it produces are
thus neither grades nor ratings. Rather, the score is strictly a measure of stringency of protection. As a
measurement tool, the TSPI simply measures. Additional empirical work or subjective assessment will
determine whether a particular measurement is associated with particular outcomes or should be assigned a
particular adjective 107.
The initial implementation of the TSPI is for a single time period for the sample countries 108.
Econometrically, this will permit cross-sectional analysis. However, in future, subject to available
resources, the index could be deepened to include multiple time periods and additional countries. This
would permit use of more powerful econometric techniques for dynamic assessments based on panel data
for a broader set of countries. Moreover, the dynamics of the protection for trade secrets could be
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
144 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
compared with those for protection of other types of intellectual property (e.g. patents) in order to gain a
more integrated view of their effects.
The development of this index is a pioneering effort in the analysis of protection of trade secrets.
However, it should be noted that a variety of similar indices exist in the literature covering various types of
intellectual property. For example, Ginarte and Park (1997) and Park (2008) employed laws-on-the-books
approaches to examine protection of patents, trademarks and copyright. Also, the Fraser Institute (2012)
and World Economic Forum (2012), among others, have developed substantial sets of relevant systemic
indicators for use in economic analyses. Such indicators have been utilised in a number of studies
conducted by the Working Party of the Trade Committee and other parts of OECD 109.
Index Composition
Chart 3.1. presents the detailed composition of the index and its scoring. The index is
structured around five main components:
1. Definitions and coverage
2. Specific duties and misappropriation
3. Remedies and restrictions on liability
4. Enforcement, investigation & discovery; data exclusivity
5. System functioning and related regulation
The approach to scoring provides up to one point for each of the five main components of the index
and a maximum total score for the index of five points. However, as can be seen in the Chart, the number
of elements covered by each of the main components of the index varies widely. For example, the
definition and coverage of trade secrets protection comprises 12 elements, whereas the system functioning
and related regulation comprises 4 elements. In order to maintain balance across the five components of the
index, the scoring for the various elements under each of the five main components was normalised to
ensure equal weighting. In other words, the elements for each main component add up to a maximum score
of one 110.
TSPI - Index Results
Table 3.1. presents – for the initial sample – the total scores by country according to
various weighting schemes. The three weighting schemes are:
1. Equal weights across the components (20% each x 5);
2. 40% for Enforcement, investigation & discovery; data exclusivity and 60% split evenly
among the other components; and
3. 40% Remedies and restrictions on liability and 60% split evenly among the other
components.
Interestingly, the three weighting schemes yield similar country rankings as shown by the high scores
for the Spearman rank correlation coefficients in the table. In other words, according to this indicator, the
use of alternative weighting schemes does not substantially change the country rankings. Thus, in the
absence of a compelling rationale for unequal weights, the authors have opted to employ equal weights 111.
Under the equal weights approach, the scores range from a low of 2.47 (Russia) to a high of 4.49
(United States). Figure 3.1. provides an overview of the scores across the countries covered in the sample
for each of the TSPI components and for the TSPI as a whole. The OECD countries tend to have relatively
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
145 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
high total scores, though partner countries such as Singapore and Malaysia have scores, respectively,
falling within or just below the OECD range. Other developing countries, including Brazil, Colombia,
South Africa and Peru, deliver total scores above 3.0. Four countries in the initial sample have total scores
below 3.0: Bulgaria, China, Russian Federation and India.
A review of the scores for the individual components of the index (Figure 3.1) reveals different
country rankings for each component, reflecting the variation in the manner countries construct and operate
their trade secrets regimes. In particular, the component for “System functioning and related regulation”
reveals a different mix of countries near the top of the rankings than for the total. For example, Sweden
emerges as having the highest score among the European nations, whereas for some other components its
relative score is lower. For certain other individual components of the index, countries such as Brazil,
Bulgaria, Colombia and Singapore appear among the top 5 or 6 countries in the rankings. With the
exception of Singapore, however, the total scores for these countries fall outside of the range for OECD
country scores. This reflects weakness in their scores for certain other components of the TSPI.
The breakdown by component reflects the particularly low scores for the Russian Federation, Brazil
and India with respect to system functioning and related regulation. This highlights implementation
challenges faced by these countries. A number of OECD countries, as well as Singapore and South Africa,
delivered relatively stringent protections in the handling of duties and misappropriation related to trade
secrets. The United States’ high score was reinforced in part by relative strengths in the components
referring to remedies and enforcement and related provisions 112.
The variation in the component scores highlights the different combinations of legal provisions and
practices that countries exhibit to arrive at a given TSPI total score. The Spearman rank correlation is
relatively high (0.828) between the scores for overall system functioning and the TSPI total scores. The
Spearman rank correlation is also relatively high (0.719) between the scores for the component “specific
duties and misappropriation” and the TSPI total scores. That is, country rankings are relatively consistent
in the scores for these two components and the TSPI total scores. However, the country rankings vary
significantly with respect to the other three components relative to their total scores. For example, a
country without criminal statutes addressing trade secrets may have a low score in remedies, but strong
scores for “specific duties and misappropriation” and “enforcement, investigation and coverage” and a
relatively high TSPI total score. Another country, may have a similar TSPI total score, but arrive at that
level via a higher score in “remedies and restrictions on liability” due in part to having criminal statutes
addressing trade secrets.
Conclusions
Anchored by a review of a broad sample of countries, this international comparative examination of
protection of trade secrets highlights the role played by the TRIPS Agreement Article 39 in orienting WTO
Member countries in the basic definition and scope of trade secrets. At the same time it underscores the
wide range of approaches employed by the sample countries in the implementation of their TRIPS
obligations with respect to protection of trade secrets. This conclusion is supported by a structured
empirical assessment of the legal regimes in the sample countries. One important contribution of this
chapter is the presentation of the underlying information drawn from the Annexes of the underlying
background paper and the taxonomy of trade secrets these materials embody. The charts and taxonomy
provide a clear, objective point-by-point basis for making comparisons among countries.
From the review of the sample countries, some specific areas of divergence can be identified. For
example, differences exist with respect to gathering of evidence, protection of trade secrets during
litigation, technology transfer and effectiveness of enforcement via the legal systems. With respect to the
procedures available for gathering evidence, some jurisdictions provide for emergency actions to preserve
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
146 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
proof, but many do not. Furthermore, no two systems of discovery are quite the same, and many are quite
weak. The ability to protect secrets during litigation also varies substantially between countries. Some
developing countries, including several BRICS, have laws intended to facilitate technology transfer, which
in some cases may cut across certain aspects of the ability to protect trade secrets. Moreover, across the
sample of countries, variation in the effectiveness of the legal systems is likely to have significant effects
on enforcement. Such diversity in protection of trade secrets can be reasonably expected to influence
firm-level decision-making.
In anticipation of subsequent analysis in Chapter 4, this chapter presents results for a preliminary
sample using a new indicator for assessing the stringency of available protection: The Trade Secrets
Protection Index (TSPI). The diversity of approaches to protection in trade secrets across the sample
countries is reflected in the scores for the TSPI, indicating that the stringency of protection for trade secrets
also varies. This variation may matter materially for the operation of firms and, hence, may influence
certain aspects of economic performance (in particular, in relation to innovation), topics that will be
considered in the coming economic analysis.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
147 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Chart 3.1. Trade Secrets Protection Index
Components and scoring
Score range
1. Definition and Coverage
0-13
Normalised score
0-1
a) Scope
•
If scope covers all confidential business information, subject
to: 1) deriving value from secrecy and 2) the owner’s
reasonable efforts to maintain secrecy, score = 1; If scope
also subject to requirement that information is imparted to
the recipient in confidence, score = ½
0,1
b) Additional Elements of Definition
•
Inventory of trade secrets required (requirement=0; no
requirement=1)
0,1
•
Must be reduced
requirement=1)
no
0,1
•
Must be identified as a trade
(requirement=0; no requirement=1)
recipient
0,1
•
Written notice to recipient required (requirement=0; no
requirement=1)
0,1
to
writing
(requirement=0;
secret
to
c) Acts covered as civil infringement:
•
Breach of duty (not covered=0, partially covered=½ 113,
covered=1)
Wrongful acquisition or misappropriation (not covered=0,
covered=1)
0,1
•
Third party liability for acquisition with knowledge or reason
to know (not available=0, available=1)
0,1
•
Third party liability for acquisition without knowledge - enjoin
“innocent parties” (not available=0, available=1)
0,1
•
0,1
d) Acts covered by criminal law
•
Breach of duty (not covered=0, partially covered=½,
covered=1)
Wrongful acquisition or misappropriation (not covered=0,
covered=1)
0,1
•
Third party liability for acquisition with knowledge or reason
to know (not available=0, available=1)
0,1
•
Third party liability for acquisition without knowledge, enjoin
“innocent parties” (not available=0, available=1)
0,1
•
0,1
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
148 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Chart 3.1.
Trade Secrets Protection Index (continued)
Components and scoring
Score range
2. Specific duties and misappropriation 114
•
Commercial relationship (covered if arising from: express
agreement ½ + implied duty ½)
0,1
•
Current employment relationship (covered if arising from:
express agreement ½ + implied duty ½)
0,1
•
Past employment relationship (covered if arising from:
express agreement ½ + implied duty ½)
0,1
•
Restrictions on post-relationship duty of confidentiality (if
any restrictions on matters beyond general skills and
knowledge, by relationship: commercial ½ + employment ½)
0,1
•
Validity of contractual restrictions on competition (if
unenforceable=0, significant limitations=½ (e.g., limited by
time or place for either commercial or post-employment
situations), generally enforceable=1)
0,1
3. Remedies and Restrictions on liability
a) Restrictions on liability
•
Additional elements of proof in infringement claims (if none:
civil=½ + criminal=½, criminal ½ point; score 1 if there no
criminal law and civil score is ½)
0,1
b) Civil remedies
•
•
Preliminary injunction (if available = 1, if not = 0)
Ex parte action available under preliminary injunction (if
available = 1, if not = 0)
0,1
0,1
•
•
Permanent injunction (if available = 1, if not = 0)
Injunction to eliminate wrongful head start (if available = 1,
if not = 0)
0,1
0,1
•
Delivery or destruction of infringing materials (if available =
1, if not = 0)
0,1
•
Compensatory damages (direct or out of pocket damages or
consideration of profits or other damages= 1)
0,1
•
Yielding of defendant’s profits (if available = 1, if not = 0)
0,1
•
Availability of punitive or statutory damages (if available =
1, if not = 0)
0,1
c) Criminal remedies
•
Fines, damages or loss of assets (if not available = 0, if
minimal per expert opinion= ½, if substantial = 1)
0,1
•
Jail sentence (if available = 1, if not = 0)
0,1
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
Normalised score
0-5
0-1
0-11
0-1
149 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Chart 3.1.
Trade Secrets Protection Index (continued)
Components and scoring
Score range
4. Enforcement, investigation and discovery;
data exclusivity
a) Enforcement, investigation and discovery
•
Emergency search to preserve and obtain proof
(unavailable=0, available but with significant restrictions= ½
(e.g., conducted solely by an official or 3rd party expert),
readily available=1)
0,1
•
Ex parte emergency search availability (unavailable=0,
available but with significant restrictions=½, readily
available=1)
0,1
•
Pre-trial discovery (unavailable=0, documentary only or
strict limitations = ½, ready availability of documentary and
interrogatories = 1)
0,1
•
Protection of confidentiality of trade secrets in litigation
(none=0, partial= ½, fully available=1)
0,1
Normalised score
0-6
0-1
0-4
0-1
b) Data exclusivity
•
•
Drugs (years: 0=0; 0.1-3=1/3; 3.1-7.9=2/3; >8=1)
Agricultural chemicals (years: 0=0, 0.1-4.9=1/3, 5-8=2/3; >
8=1)
0,1
0,1
5. System functioning and related regulation
•
Technology transfer: registration requirement (none=1; one
or more = 0)
0,1
•
Technology transfer: substantive review or regulation
(none=1; one or more = 0)
0,1
•
Fraser Institute score for Legal System and Security of
Property Rights (score ranging from 0 to 10, divided by
10) 115
Expert characterisation of the operation of the protection in
practice (NB, based on internationally recognised or peerreviewed sources; see country charts for details)
(Negative = 0; none = ½; positive = 1)
0,1
•
Index Total
0,1
======
0-5
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
Figure 3.1.
150 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Trade Secrets Protection Index, by component and country, 2010
Note: The data for this figure reflect updates prepared for Chapter 4 and therefore differ slightly from the results presented in the original background
paper (Schultz and Lippoldt, 2014).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
151 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Table 3.1. Trade Secret Protection Index, Statistics and Total Scores, Alternate Weights, 2010
Country
Australia
Brazil
Bulgaria
China
Colombia
France
Germany
India
Israel
Italy
Japan
Korea
Malaysia
New Zealand
Peru
Russian Federation
Singapore
South Africa
Sweden
United Kingdom
United States
Average Score
Max
Median
Min
Standard Deviation
Coefficient of Variation
Correlation
Coefficient
(equal
weight
scores
versus alternate schemes)
Spearman
Rank
Correlation (equal weight
ranking versus alternate
schemes)
Total Scores, by weighting scheme
Equal weights;
20% for each
component
3,99
3,31
2,96
2,71
3,15
3,76
3,76
2,92
4,08
3,85
4,27
3,81
3,48
4,04
3,06
2,47
4,00
3,14
3,56
3,97
4,49
40%
for
Enforcement,
investigation
&
discovery;
data
exclusivity;
60%
divided
equally
among the other
components
4,07
3,42
3,37
2,72
2,84
3,75
3,55
2,99
4,13
3,93
4,04
3,41
3,48
4,04
3,06
2,48
4,01
2,98
3,40
4,12
4,55
40% for Remedies
and restrictions on
liability;
60%
divided
equally
among the other
components
3,79
3,56
2,68
2,71
3,04
3,61
3,73
3,10
3,85
3,85
4,22
3,88
3,46
4,00
3,09
2,87
3,86
3,27
3,58
3,71
4,62
3,56
4,49
3,76
2,47
0,55
0,15
3,54
4,55
3,48
2,48
0,55
0,16
3,55
4,62
3,61
2,68
0,50
0,14
0,949
0,950
0,930
0,939
Note: The data for this figure reflect updates prepared for Chapter 4 and therefore differ slightly from the
results presented in the original background paper (Schultz and Lippoldt, 2014).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
152 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
NOTES
85
This chapter is based on OECD Trade Policy Paper No. 162 (Schultz & Lippoldt, 2014). There are two
substantial annexes available in the original edition. Annex 1 provides a snapshot of the key elements of trade
secret protection in each of the sample countries. Annex 2 provides a detailed overview of trade secrets
protection in the BRICS and OECD countries covered by the sample.
86
These paragraph references refer to paragraphs 2 and 3 of Article 39 of the TRIPS Agreement.
87
At this point in the original text, there is a footnote, numbered 10, that states:
For the purpose of this provision, “a manner contrary to honest commercial practices” shall mean at least
practices such as breach of contract, breach of confidence and inducement to breach, and includes the
acquisition of undisclosed information by third parties who knew, or were grossly negligent in failing to
know, that such practices were involved in the acquisition.
88
Moreover, as Pooley (1997) notes, the idea need not be unique to its owner. Several competitors could have
developed the same idea via independent innovation and sought to protect it as a trade secret. This
possibility is one factor differentiating trade secrets from patents.
89
For descriptive convenience this chapter will employ the term “trade secrets” as encompassing “undisclosed
information.”
90
The Paris Convention entered into force on 26 April 1970. These articles remained unchanged in the
subsequent edition of the Paris Convention (1979).
91
Ruckelshaus v. Monsanto Co., 467 U.S. 986, 1002-1003 (1984).
92
Ibid.
93
For example, barriers to accurate quantification include issues such as lack of internationally-standardised
valuation methodology for undisclosed information and reluctance of many firms to identify publicly the
value of their secret assets.
94
The roadmap is available on-line at the following location (as of 3 April 2013):
http://ec.europa.eu/governance/impact/planned_ia/docs/2013_markt_002_trade_secrets_en.pdf.
95
This strategy is available on-line at the following location (as of 3 April 2013):
http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/IPEC/admin_strategy_on_mitigating_the_theft_of_u.s.
_trade_secrets.pdf.
96
Pooley (1997, 2012 update, p. 34) notes contrasts between patents and trade secrets with respect to subject
matter, requirements, definition, disclosure, protection, duration, expense, risk and marketability. He also
points out (ibid, p. 40) that depending on the nature of the innovation the choice between copyright and
trade secret protection may be easier for innovators: copyright protects only the form of expression of
your ideas, whereas trade secrets protection extends to the idea itself.
97
The United States recently incorporated a prior user rights defence into its patent law with the passage of
the America Invents Act in 35 U.S.C. § 273, which may provide protection to independent inventors in
certain, limited circumstances. However, independent invention after the date that a patent is filed never
constitutes a defence.
98
Litigation statistics are not covered directly in the proposed assessment. This is in part due to lack of
readily-available information for many countries. For example, while US legal records are searchable via
systems such as Pacer or Lexis, the coverage of such systems varies significantly across countries around
the world. Many countries do not have the capacity to provide ready on-line access to court case
information. This would be a practical limit on the ability to ensure extensive geographic coverage for
purposes of the present study. In addition, litigation statistics present difficulties in interpretation related
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
153 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
to institutional context. For example, without additional contextual information, it may not be clear
whether a low number of cases indicates that compliance is high, enforcement is lax or another factor is
driving developments. Thus, such an assessment could prove resource intensive to implement. While in
principle a review of legal case outcomes has the potential to yield new insights into court-related aspects
of trade secret enforcement, such an approach was determined to exceed the scope of the present analysis.
99
The various elements of trade secrets protection retained for the present analysis are characterised
individually and in combination. In the discussion and annexes for this report, data on the various
elements are reported and may be employed for further analyses either separately or in various alternative
combinations.
100
Laws that only incidentally sanction trade secret theft were not covered. For example, theft, breaking and
entering, trespass, extortion, battery and other wrongful acts may be committed in the course of
appropriating trade secrets, and various laws sanction such acts. However, such laws are only relevant
where they sanction such acts because they involve trade secrets. For example, this project would not
account for a law that imposes liability for the theft of a sheet of paper if that law does not address the
existence or value of the trade secret printed on that piece of paper.
101
For example, common law jurisprudence may contain definitions and standards that are as clear, precise
and well-established as those in civil codes. Courts in several common law countries consistently cite and
apply a three factor definition of trade secrecy established in the English case of Coco v. A.N. Clark
Eng'rs Ltd., [1969] RPC 41: “First, the information must itself … must ‘have the necessary quality of
confidence about it.’ Secondly, that information must have been imparted in circumstances importing an
obligation of confidence. Thirdly, there must be an unauthorised use of that information to the detriment
of the party communicating it.” See Annex 1 and Annex 2 of Schultz & Lippoldt (2014) for further
details.
102
In another example, civil law systems may evolve approaches to a new problem as clearly and readily as
do common law systems. For example, since 2000 French courts have increasingly extended the offense
of “breach of trust” under Article 314-1 of the French Criminal Code to cover intangible information, thus
allowing the prosecution of employees and others for trade secret misappropriation. See Christophe Garin,
“Customer poaching can now be punished by criminal courts on the ground of breach of trust,” Lexology
(24 May 2012) at: www.lexology.com/library/detail.aspx?g=e11830fd-5222-4084-afdd-a160047f2fec .
See Annex 2 of Schultz & Lippoldt (2014) for further details.
103
For example, specific provisions of French criminal law sanction the disclosure of technical information
by employees and managers, but not confidential business information. However, in recent years
generally-applicable provisions of French criminal law have been used to prosecute the disclosure and
misappropriation of confidential business information, so the distinction may be fading in this particular
instance.
104
The OECD has also considered this issue in the context of knowledge networks and markets. For
example, a paper on Knowledge Flows and the Mobility of Skilled Employees: An International
Perspective on the Role of Non-Compete Agreements and their Legal Enforcement examined these issues
in 2012 [DSTI/EAS/STP/NESTI/TIP(2012)10, Fernando Galindo-Rueda].
105
While there is some variation among countries in the specifics of such protection, in the case of agricultural
chemicals many developed countries have established minimum effective terms of five to ten years.
106
For a comprehensive, recent review of these laws, see Padmashree Gehl Sampath and Pedro Roffe,
“Unpacking the International Technology Transfer Debate: Fifty Years and Beyond,” ICTSD Working
Paper (June 2012), available at: http://ictsd.org/downloads/2012/07/unpacking-the-internationaltechnology-transfer-debate-fifty-years-and-beyond.pdf (as of 15 August 2013).
107
The index avoids summative descriptive assessments such as whether protection is “comprehensive” or
“well-established.” The accumulation of elements and the resulting score speaks to such issues more
precisely than any subjective assessment, and does so in a replicable, generalisable manner.
108
Due to a lack of recent-period data for some countries, 2010 is the most recent year covered by this
iteration of the TSPI. Therefore, please note that events may occur subsequent to the period covered here.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
154 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
There is an on-going court case in Europe, for example, that has potential implications for certain aspects
of the balance of rights between protection of commercially sensitive information submitted to public
authorities and access to information relevant to environmental concerns. See Judgment of the General
Court of the European Union, Case T-545/11, Stichting Greenpeace Nederland and PAN Europe v
European Commission (8 October 2013).
109
Several Trade Committee studies considered policies for protection of intellectual property rights in
relation
to
relevant
economic
performance
indicators.
OLIS
references
include:
TD/TC/WP(2003)10/FINAL,
TD/TC/WP(2004)31/FINAL,
TAD/TC/WP(2007)19/FINAL
and
TAD/TC/WP(2010)12/FINAL. Subsequent OECD Trade Policy Working Papers were published as: Park
and Lippoldt (2003); Park and Lippoldt (2005); Park and Lippoldt (2008); and Cavazos, Lippoldt and
Senft (2010).
110
For example, component 4 Enforcement, investigation and discovery; data exclusivity is comprised of six
elements. The value for the component 4 score can range from 0 to one. In the final calculation of the
score for the overall component, the scores for any given element would be no more than 1/6 of one point.
This would be the case, for example, for data exclusivity for drugs or data exclusivity for agricultural
chemicals (each would contribute no more than 1/6 of one point to the component score).
111
A similar weighting approach and rational was employed by Ginarte and Park in developing their widelycited Patent Rights Index. See Ginarte and Park (1997, pp. 288-89) for their discussion of weighting
considerations.
112
Annex Table A1 (Annex 1) in Schultz & Lippoldt (2014) provides the detailed scoring for each element and
component of the index for each country. In the event a user would like to consider alternative approaches
to constructing indicators, these data will provide the essential building blocks (e.g., for recombining
various elements or reweighting the components).
113
E.g. the duty of confidentiality might be imposed on employees, fiduciaries and third parties with access to
information. Partial coverage might arise if under a country’s legal regime licensees cannot be covered.
114
The treatment of duties is split within this framework. General coverage of duties is scored under index
component 1 (Definitions & Coverage). Component 2 responds to the availability of recourse for specific
duties. This permits a detailed assessment, ensuring the indicator responds to variation in key elements.
115
The Fraser Institute (2012, pp. 3 and 273-5) score for Legal System and Security of Property Rights is a
composite indicator produced annually. Scores can range from 0 to 10. Based on objective indicators and
expert assessments, it takes into account judicial independence, impartiality of courts, protection of property
rights, military interference in the rule of law and politics, integrity of the legal system, legal enforcement of
contracts, regulatory restrictions on the sale of real property, reliability of the police and business costs of
crime. For details see Annex 1 of the original report (Schultz and Lippoldt, 2014) and
www.freetheworld.com/reports.html.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
155 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
REFERENCES
This annotated reference list reviews the main material from the legal and economic literature on trade
secrets. The OECD team has added annotations based on their assessments: key articles are marked with an
asterisk (*) and many of the references have comments in italics on the nature or utility of the item.
Appended to the references from the literature is a reference listing of key laws and precedent.
Overview: Literature References
This initial scan of the literature found that the economic literature on trade secrets is relatively
limited in quantity and scope. It largely falls into three categories: i) fundamental economic theories of
trade secret law; ii) theoretical and empirical examination of the trade-offs between patent and trade secret
protection; and iii) theoretical and empirical examination of how trade secrecy protection affects firm
structure and employee relationships. The legal literature is more expansive in terms of quantity, although
much of it is somewhat distant for the purposes of the present project with respect to assessment of
economic implications. Also, the United States legal regime for trade secrets is disproportionately
represented in the literature.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
156 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
LITERATURE REFERENCES
AIPPI (1994), Resolution on Question 115 Effective protection against unfair competition under
Article 10bis Paris Convention of 1883, International Association for the Protection of
Intellectual Property (AIPPI), available as of 15 November 2013 at:
https://www.aippi.org/download/commitees/115/RS115English.pdf .
Almeling, D.S. et al. (2009), “A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in Federal Courts,”
45 Gonzaga Law Review 291. Descriptive survey of US law.
Almeling, D.S. et al. (2010), “A Statistical Analysis of Trade Secret Litigation in State Courts,”
46 Gonzaga Law Review 57. Descriptive survey of US law.
AmCham China (2013), “China Business Climate Survey Report: 2013”, The American Chamber of
Commerce in the People’s Republic of China, Beijing.
AMCham Korea (2004), Intellectual Property Rights, American Chamber of Commerce in Korea,
available as of 13 August 2013 at:
www.amchamkorea.org/publications/2004ikbc/Intellectual%20Property%20Rights.doc
Ampollini, D. (2010), “Italy” in C. Noorda and S. Hanlose (eds.), E-Discovery and Data Privacy: A
Practical Guide, Kluwer Law International, Alphen aan den Rijn, The Netherlands.
Anawalt, H.C. (2011), Idea rights: a guide to intellectual property, Carolina Academic Press,
Durham, N.C.
Anawalt, H.C. & West Group (2011), IP strategy: complete intellectual property planning, access
and protection, Thomson Reuters/Westlaw, St. Paul, MN.
Andrews, N.H. (1987), “Abuse of Anton Piller Orders,” The Cambridge Law Journal, 46(1), pp. 5052.
Aplin, T. & F. Gurry (2012), Gurry on Breach of Confidence: The Protection of Confidential
Information, Section, Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.
Arrow, K.J. (1962), “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention”, in The Rate
and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors, 609, 615, National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Arundel, A. (2001), “The Relative Effectiveness of Patents and Secrecy for Appropriation,” 30
Research Policy, 611–624.
Arundel, A., G. van de Paal & L. Soete (1995), “Innovation Strategies of Europe’s Largest Industrial
Firms: Results of the PACE Survey,” Directorate General XIII, European Commission, EIMS
Publication 23.
ASIS (2007), Trends in Proprietary Information Loss: Survey Report, American Society for
Industrial Security, ASIS International.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
157 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Bai, J.B. & G. Da (2011), “Strategies for Trade Secrets Protection in China,” Northwestern Journal
of Technology and Intellectual Property, 9:351.
Band, T. & I. Miller (2010), Question Q215: Protection of Trade Secrets Through IPR and Unfair
Competition Law, AIPPI Report on Israel.
Bechtold, S. & F. Hoffler (2011), “An Economic Analysis of Trade-Secret Protection in Buyer-Seller
Relationships,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 27(1), 137-158.
Bernhardt, D. & V. Dvoracek (2009), “Preservation of Trade Secrets and Multinational Wage
Premia,” Economic Inquiry, 47.4, 726-738.
Biger, N. & S.E. Plaut (2000), “Trade Secrets, Firm-Specific Human Capital, and Optimal
Contracting,” European Journal of Law and Economics, 9.1, 49-71.
Blood, C.G. (2002), “Holding Foreign Nations Civilly Accountable for Their Economic Espionage
Practices,” 42 IDEA 227.
* Bone, R.G. (1998), “A New Look at Trade Secret Law: Doctrine in Search of Justification,” 86
California Law Review, 241. Seminal work in the legal literature on trade secret doctrine.
Bone, R.G. (2011), “Trade Secrecy, Innovation and the Requirement of Reasonable Secrecy
Precautions”, in R.C. Dreyfuss and K.J. Strandburg (eds.), The Law and Theory of Trade
Secrecy: A Handbook of Contemporary Research, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Brant, J. & S. Lohse (2013), “Enhancing Intellectual Property Management and Appropriation by
Innovative SMEs,” Innovation and Intellectual Property Series, Research Paper No. 1,
International Chamber of Commerce.
Budylin, S. & Y. Osipova (2007), “Total Upgrade: Intellectual Property Law Reform in Russia,”
Colum. J.E. Eur. L. 1:1.
Burk, D.L. et al. (2007), “The Goldilocks Hypothesis: Balancing Intellectual Property Rights at the
Boundary of the Firm,” University of Illinois Law Review, 575.
Carvalho, N.P.d. (2008), The TRIPS regime of antitrust and undisclosed information, Kluwer Law
International, Frederick, MD.
Castro, C.R.S. et al. (2012), “Latin Lawyer: Litigation 2013: Brazil”, available as of 14 August 2013
at: http://latinlawyer.com/reference/topics/60/jurisdictions/6/brazil/.
Cavazos Cepeda, R., D. Lippoldt & J. Senft (2010), “Policy Complements to the Strengthening of
IPRS in Developing Countries”, OECD Trade Policy Papers, No. 104, OECD Publishing,
[TAD/TC/WP(2010)12/FINAL].
CEFIC (2012), Report on the Importance of Trade Secrets for Chemical Companies, The European
Chemical Industry Council, 15 November.
Cheung, S.N.S. (1982), “Property Rights in Trade Secrets,” Economic Inquiry, 20, 40-53.
Chiappetta, V. (1999), “Myth, Chameleon or Intellectual Property Olympian - A Normative
Framework Supporting Trade Secret Law,” 8 George Mason Law Review, 69.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
158 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
City Law School (2008), Employment Law in Practice Section, Oxford University Press, Oxford,
UK.
Claeys, E.R. (2013), “Intellectual Usufructs: Trade Secrets, Hot News, and the Usufructuary
Paradigm at Common Law,” in S. Balganesh (ed.), Intellectual Property and the Common
Law, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom.
Claeys, E.R. (2011), “Private Law Theory and Corrective Justice in Trade Secrecy,” 4 Journal of
Tort Law, Article 2.
Claeys, E.R. (2010), “The Use Requirement at Common Law and Under the Uniform Trade Secrets
Act,” 33 Hamline Law Review, 583. Explains use requirement and normative justification for
it.
Cohen, W., R. Nelson & J. Walsh (2000), “Protecting their Intellectual Assets: Appropriability
Conditions and Why U.S. Manufacturing Firms Patent (Or Not),” NBER Working Paper,
W7552, http://www.nber.org/papers/w7552.pdf.
Colston, C. & J. Galloway (2010), Modern Intellectual Property Law, Routledge, London, UK.
Corrado, C., C. Hulten and D. Sichel (2009), “Intangible Capital and Economic Growth”, Review of
Income and Wealth, Series 55, Number 3, September, pp. 661-685.
Correa, C. (2002), “Unfair Competition under the Trips Agreement: Protection of Data Submitted for
the Registration of Pharmaceuticals,” 3 Chi. J. Int'l L. 69.
Correa, C.M. (2011), “Test data protection: rights conferred under the TRIPS Agreement and some
effects of TRIPS-plus standards,” in R.C. Dreyfuss and K.J. Strandburg (eds.), The Law and
Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of Contemporary Research, Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham, UK.
Cugno, F. & E. Ottoz (2006), “Trade Secret vs. Broad Patent: The Role Of Licensing,” Review Of
Law And Economics, 2.2, 209-221.
Czapracka, K.A. (2007), “Antitrust and Trade Secrets: The U.S. and the EU Approach,” 24 Santa
Clara Computer & High Tech Law Journal, 207.
Di Blasi, G. (2009), “Data Exclusivity Protection in Brazil,” World Intellectual Property Review 32,
November/December, available as of 13 August 2013 at:
http://www.pedrofolio.com/clientes/diblasi/arquivos_pdf/724.pdf.
Dratler, J., Jr. (1990), Trade Secrets in the United States and Japan: A Comparison and Prognosis,
14 Yale J. Int'l L. 68.
Dreyfuss, R.C. & K.J. Strandburg (2011), “Introduction”, in R.C. Dreyfuss and K.J. Strandburg
(eds.), The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of Contemporary Research,
Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
* Dreyfuss, R.C. & K.J. Strandburg (eds.) (2011), The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A
Handbook of Contemporary Research, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. Collection of papers
highlighting a broad range of trade secrets issues ranging from the foundational concepts, to
the balance between secrecy and sharing, and the relationship to other public policy areas.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
159 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
EC (2013), Study on Trade Secrets and Confidential Business Information in the Internal Market,
prepared for the European Commission (EC) by Baker and McKenzie, April, available at this
link (as of 8 August 2013):
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/iprenforcement/trade_secrets/index_en.htm#maincontentSec1
.
Eisenberg, R.S. (2011), “Data Secrecy in the Age of Regulatory Exclusivity”, in R.C. Dreyfuss and
K.J. Strandburg (eds.), The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of Contemporary
Research, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Ellery, T. & N. Hansen (2012), Pharmaceutical Lifecycle Management: Making the Most of Each
and Every Brand, Wiley & Sons, Hoboken, N.J., USA.
EOP (2013), Administration Strategy on Mitigating the Theft of U.S. Trade Secrets, The Executive
Office of the President of the United States (EOP), available as of 29 March 2013 at:
http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/IPEC/admin_strategy_on_mitigating_the_t
heft_of_u.s._trade_secrets.pdf, February.
Fekete, E.K. et al. (2010), AIPPI Report Q215, Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair
Competition Law, Brazil.
Feldman, Y. (2003), “Experimental Approach to the Study of Normative Failures: Divulging of Trade
Secrets by Silicon Valley Employees,” University of Illinois, Journal of Law, Technology and
Policy, 105.
Fellmeth, A.X. (2004), “Secrecy, Monopoly, and Access to Pharmaceuticals in International Trade
Law: Protection of Marketing Approval Data under the TRIPs Agreement,” 45 Harvard
International Law Journal, 443.
Fraser Institute (2012), Economic Freedom of the World 2012 Annual Report, J. Gwartney, R.
Lawson & J. Hall, available as of 15 August 2013 at:
http://www.freetheworld.com/reports.html.
* Friedman, D.D., W.M. Landes and R.A. Posner (1991), “Some Economics of Trade Secret Law,”
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5 (Winter), pp. 61-72. This seminal paper on the law and
economics of trade secrets, sets forth the basic and frequently cited intuitions and models
regarding the patent-trade secret trade off and the incentive created by trade secrets.
Fukao, K., T. Miyagawa, K. Mukai, Y. Shinoda and K. Tonogi (2008), “Intangible Investment in
Japan: New Estimates and Contribution to Economic Growth,” RIETI Discussion Paper, 07-E034, as revised, June.
Gallié, E-P. & D. Legros (2012), “French firms’ strategies for protecting their intellectual property”,
41:2 Research Policy 780.
Garin, C. (2012), “Customer Poaching Can Now be Punished by Criminal Courts on the Ground of
Breach of Trust,” Lexology, 24 May, available as of 13 August 2013 at:
http://www.lexology.com/library/detail.aspx?g=e11830fd-5222-4084-afdd-a160047f2fec
Ghidini, G. & V. Falce (2011), Trade secrets as intellectual property rights: a disgraceful upgrading
- Notes on an Italian 'reform’, in R.C. Dreyfuss and K.J. Strandburg (eds.), The Law and
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
160 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of Contemporary Research, Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham, UK.
Ghildiyal, S. (2012), Govt working on norms to protect trade secrets, The Times of India, 29
November, available as of 14 August 2013 at:
http://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/business/india-business/Govt-working-on-norms-to-protecttrade-secrets/articleshow/17409936.cms.
Gilson, R.J. (1999), “The Legal Infrastructure of High Technology Industrial Districts: Silicon
Valley, Route 128, and Covenants Not To Compete,” 74 New York University Law Review,
575.
Ginarte, J.C. & W. G. Park (1997), “Determinants of Patent Rights: A Cross-National Study,”
Research Policy, Vol. 26, 283-301.
Goodman, C.F. (2004), “Japan’s New Civil Procedure Code: Has It Fostered A Rule Of Law Dispute
Resolution Mechanism?”, Brook. J. Int’l L., 29:511.
Gorodissky Law Firm, (2012), “IP Legislation News,” 21 August, available as of 13 August 2013 at:
http://www.gorodissky.com/law_news/?newsid=34.
Graham, S. J. H., & T. Sichelman (2008), “Why Do Start‐Ups Patent?,” Berkeley Technology Law
Journal 23(3), pp. 1063‐1097.
Graham, S. J. H., R. Merges, P. Samuelson, & T. Sichelman (2010), “High Technology
Entrepreneurs and the Patent System: Results of the 2008 Berkeley Patent Survey,” Berkeley
Technology Law Journal 24(4), pp. 1255‐1328.
Graves, C.T. (2011a), “Analyzing The Non-Competition Covenant as a Category of Intellectual
Property Regulation,” 3 Hastings Science and Technology Law Journal, 69.
Graves, C.T. (2011b), “Trade secrecy and common law confidentiality: the problem of multiple
regimes”, in R.C. Dreyfuss and K.J. Strandburg (eds.), The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy:
A Handbook of Contemporary Research, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Graves, C.T. & J.A. DiBoise (2007), “Do Strict Trade Secret and Non-Competition Laws Obstruct
Innovation?,” 1 Ohio State Entrepreneurial Business Law Journal, 231.
Grishchenkova, A. (June 2012), “The Discovery Process in Russia. Will the New Era Come?,” FBK
Legal, available as of 14 August 2013 at:
http://www.legal500.com/developments/20074.
Grubbs, S.R. (ed.) (2003), International Civil Procedure, Kluwer Law International, The Hague,
Netherlands.
Hailing, S (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215, China.
Hall, B. H., C. Helmers, M. L. Rogers & V. Sena (2012), “The Choice Between Formal and Informal
Intellectual Property: A Literature Review,” NBER Working Paper No. w17983. Available at
SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2035782 (as of 31 October 2012).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
161 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
* Hogan Lovells (2012), Study on Trade Secrets and Parasitic Copying (Look-alikes),
MARKT/2010/20/D, Report on Trade Secrets for the European Commission, Hogan Lovells
International LLP. This review of protection of trade secrets in the European Union is an
excellent source of baseline information.
Instituto Mexicano de la Propriedad Industrial (2013), “Protección De Los Secretos Industriales En
México, Conforme A Los Parámetros Del Documento.”
Ivanov, Y., “Non-Compete Clause in Russia: Do the Laws Compete?,” The Moscow Times, 16
October 2008, available as of 14 August 2013 at:
http://www.themoscowtimes.com/business_for_business/article/non-compete-clause-in-russiado-the-laws-compete/371717.html#ixzz2RnClzTM9 .
Jager, M.F. (2012), Trade Secrets Law, Thompson-Reuters, Westlaw. This is a comprehensive legal
treatise.
Johnson, E.E. (2010), “Trade Secret Subject Matter,” 33 Hamline Law Review, 545.
Jones, J (2007), “Data exclusivity provisions under the Therapeutic Goods Act 1989,” available as of
14 August 2013 at: http://www.davies.com.au/pub/detail/234/data-exclusivity-provisionsunder-the-therapeutic-goods-act-1989.
Khabarov, D.I. (2012), “Intellectual Property – Russia,” International Law Office, January.
Kim, H.S. (2011), “Trade secret law, intellectual property, and innovation: Theoretical, empirical,
and Asian perspectives,” PhD Thesis, University of Illinois.
Kim, S.R. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215, Korea.
* Kitch, E.W. (1980), “The Law and Economics of Rights in Valuable Information,” 9 Journal of
Legal Studies, 683. Another seminal article.
Knobel, J. (2000), “Wrongfulness Of Trade Secret Misappropriation; and Trade Secrets As Objects
Of Subjective Rights,” Acta Juridica 2000:196.
Koch, M. (2006), Non-competition clauses in labour contracts, Sweden, Report for the XIVth
Meeting of European Labour Court Judges, available as of 14 August 2013 at:
http://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/@ed_dialogue/@dialogue/documents/meetingdocu
ment/wcms_159972.pdf.
Lai, E. L-C., R. Riezman & P. Wang (2009), “Symposium on Organization, Heterogeneity and
Trade: Outsourcing of Innovation,” Economic Theory, 38.3, 485-515.
Landes, W.M. & R.A. Posner (2003), “The Economics of Trade Secrecy Law,” in the Economic
Structure of Intellectual Property Law, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. A follow up
to and summary of a 1991 article.
* Landes, W.M. & R.A. Posner (2003), The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law,
Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Lang, J. (2003), “The Protection of Commercial Trade Secrets,” European Intellectual Property
Review, 10:462.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
162 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Lee, H.P. & E. Campbell (2013), The Australian Judiciary, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,
UK.
Leiponen, A. & J. Byma (2009), “If You Cannot Block, You Better Run: Small Firms, Cooperative
Innovation, And Appropriation Strategies,” Research Policy, 38.9, 1478-1488.
* Lemley, M.A. (2008), “The Surprising Virtues of Treating Trade Secrets as IP Rights”, 61 Stanford
Law Review, 311. This paper contends that trade secret law leads to greater spillovers and
more information sharing because the presence of the law leads owners to forego more
restrictive forms of physical or other security.
Lemley, M.A. (2011), “The Surprising Virtues of Treating Trade Secrets as IP rights”, in R.C.
Dreyfuss and K.J. Strandburg (eds.), The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of
Contemporary Research, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
* Lerner, J. (1994), “The Importance of Trade Secrecy: Evidence from Civil Litigation,” unpublished
manuscript, Harvard University,
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=6089. Establishes importance of trade secrets to
SMEs in the United States.
Lester, G. (2001), “Restrictive Covenants, Employee Training, and the Limits of Transaction-Cost
Analysis,” 76 Indiana Law Journal, 49.
Levin, M. et al. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215, Sweden.
Levine, D. (2010), “What Can the Uniform Trade Secrets Act Learn From the Bayh Dole Act,” 33
Hamline Law Review, 615.
Liang, D. (April 2008), “The Interplay of Non-compete Covenants under the PRC Anti-monopoly
Law,” King Wood & Mallesons China Bulletin, available as of 14 August 2013 at:
http://www.kingandwood.com/article.aspx?id=The-Interplay-of-Non-compete-Covenants-under-thePRC-Anti-monopoly-Law-04-china-bulletin-2008&language=en.
Lippoldt, D.C. (2011), Patent Rights, Developing Countries and the Economic Influence of the
Multilateral Trading System, SciencesPo, Paris,
http://spire.sciences-po.fr/hdl:/2441/f4rshpf3v1umfa09lass9h1s2.
Liuzzo, L. et al. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215, Italy.
MacLaren, T. (2012), Trade Secrets Throughout the World, database update, Thomson/West, Eagan,
MN, USA.
Maleshin, D. (2007), “The Russian Style of Civil Procedure,” Emory Int'l L. Rev. 21:543.
Malsberger, B.M., R.A. Blackstone and A.H. Pedowitz (2006), Trade Secrets: A State-by-State
Survey, Bureau of National Affairs, Washington D.C.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
163 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Maskus, K. E. (2000), Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Economy, Institute for International
Economics.
Maskus, K.E. (2012), Private Rights and Public Problems: The Global Economics of Intellectual
Property in the 21st Century, Peterson Institute for International Economics.
McAfee (2009), Unsecured Economies: Protecting Vital Information.
McAfee (2011), Underground Economies: Intellectual Capital And Sensitive Corporate Data Now
The Latest Cybercrime Currency.
MacLaren, T. (2013), Eckstrom's Licensing in Foreign and Domestic Operations: Joint Ventures,
database update, Thomson/West, St. Paul, MN, USA.
McGuire, M. et al., Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215.
* Merges, R.P. (1999), “The Law and Economics of Employee Inventions”, 13 Harvard Journal of
Law and Technology, 1. An important theoretical work on the interaction of trade secret law
with ownership of employee inventions.
Milgrim, R.M. & E.E. Bensen (1997), Milgrim on trade secrets, M. Bender, New York, NY.
Comprehensive legal treatise.
Moohr, G.S. (2002), “The Problematic Role of Criminal Law in Regulating Use of Information: The
Case of the Espionage Act,” 80 North Carolina Law Review, 853.
Nemec, D. & K. Voorhees (2013), “Recent amendment to the Economic Espionage Act extends
protection against misappropriation, Thomson Reuters News & Insight, 13 February.
OECD (2010), Measuring Innovation: A New Perspective.
OECD (2011), New sources of growth: intangible assets, a flyer available on-line:
http://www.oecd.org/sti/inno/46349020.pdf.
Office of the National Counterintelligence Executive Report (2011), Foreign Spies Stealing US
Economic Secrets in Cyberspace.
Osakwe, C. (2008), Russian Civil Code. Parts 1 -3: Text and Analysis, Wolters Kluwer, Moscow,
Russia.
Paalanen-Koev, H. (2012), Corporate Counsel’s Guide to Doing Business in Russia, Thomson/West,
St. Paul, MN, USA.
Park, W.G. (2008), “International Patent Protection: 1960-2005”, Research Policy, No. 37, 761-766.
Park, W.G. & D.C. Lippoldt (2003), “The Impact of Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights on
Trade and Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries”, OECD Papers, Vol. 3, No. 11,
paper 294, [TD/TC/WP(2003)10/FINAL].
Park, W.G. & D.C. Lippoldt (2005), “International Licensing and the Strengthening of Intellectual
Property Rights in Developing Countries”, OECD Trade Policy Working Paper #10, Paris,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
164 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
[TD/TC/WP(2004)31/FINAL]. (This paper was further developed and released in OECD
Economic Studies, 2005, Vol. 40.)
Park, W.G. & D.C. Lippoldt (2008), Technology Transfer and the Economic Implications of the
Strengthening of Intellectual Property Rights in Developing Countries, OECD Trade Policy
Paper, Number 62, OECD, January, [TAD/TC/WP(2007)19/FINAL].
PhRMA (2013), Special 301 Submission 2013, available as of 14 August 2013 at:
http://www.phrma.org/sites/default/files/pdf/PhRMA%20Special%20301%20Submission%20
2013.pdf
Png, I. (2012a), Law and Innovation: Evidence from State Trade Secrets Laws, mimeo, National
University of Singapore, SSRN.
* Png, I. (2012b), “Trade Secrets, Non-Competes, and Mobility of Engineers and Scientists:
Empirical Evidence”, mimeo, National University of Singapore, SSRN. Creates and uses a
small index of trade secret strength.
Pooley, J. (1997), Trade Secrets, Law Journal Seminars-Press, New York, NY. Comprehensive legal
treatise, with annual supplements.
Practical Law Company (April 2013), “IP in business transactions: South Africa overview”,
available as of 14 August 2013 at: http://uk.practicallaw.com/6-519-5891#a480193.
Quinto, D.W. & S.H. Singer (2009), Trade secrets: law and practice, Oxford University Press, NY.
Rajbhandary, A. (1996), “Protecting Trade Secrets Through Family Businesses: A Case Study On
Nepal,” International Review of Law and Economics, 16.4, 483-490.
Rapsinews (2011), “Court allows BP not to disclose information on Rosneft deal,” 10 October,
available as of 14 August 2013 at:
http://www.rapsinews.com/judicial_news/20111010/256186687.html.
Rapsinews (2011), “Coal producer secures hearing for suit against antimonopoly service,” 30
September, available as of 14 August 2013 at:
http://www.rapsinews.com/judicial_news/20110930/255926069.html/
Reagan, T. & J. Cort (2009), Sealed Cases in Federal Courts, Federal Judicial Center, available as of
14 August 2013 at:
http://www.fjc.gov/public/pdf.nsf/lookup/sealcafc.pdf/$file/sealcafc.pdf
Reddy, P. (2013), “The Data Exclusivity Debate in India: Time for a rethink?,” available as of 14
August 2013 at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2231027 .
Reuters, “German Spy Chief Targets Russian, Chinese Industrial Espionage,” 18 February 2013, at:
http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/02/18/us-germany-spies-idUSBRE91H08C20130218
Revue Lamy Droit de L'immatériel (2007) No. 27, 05-2007.
Risch, M. (2012), “An Empirical Look at Trade Secret Law’s Shift from Common to Statutory Law,”
in S. Balganesh (ed.), Intellectual Property and the Common Law. Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
165 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
* Risch, M. (2011), “Trade secret law and information development incentives”, in R.C. Dreyfuss
and K.J. Strandburg (eds.), The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of
Contemporary Research, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Risch, M. (2010), “A Failure of Uniform Laws?”, 159 University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 1
Risch, M. (2009), “Comments on Trade Secrets Sharing in High Velocity Labor Markets,” 12
Employment Rights and Employment Policy Journal, 339.
* Risch, M. (2007), “Why Do We Have Trade Secrets,” 11 Marquette Intellectual Property Law
Review, 1. This author contends that the most important marginal incentive created by trade
secrets is to reduce wasteful spending on security or circumventing security. He argues that
trade secret law provides a less important marginal incentive to invest in R&D because it
requires secrecy, and where parties can keep an innovation secret, they already have an
incentive to innovate without trade secret law.
Ronde, T. (2001), “Trade Secrets and Information Sharing”, Journal of Economics & Management
Strategy, 10, 391-417.
Rowe, E & S.K. Sandeen (2012), Rowe and Sandeen’s Cases and Materials on Trade Secret Law,
Thomson Reuters/Westlaw, St. Paul, MN.
* Samuelson, P. & S. Scotchmer (2002), “The Law and Economics of Reverse Engineering,” 111
Yale Law Journal, 1575. A well-cited article on the theory supporting the allowance of reverse
engineering.
Sandeen, S.K. (2011), “The limits of trade secret law: Article 39 of the TRIPS Agreement and the
Uniform Trade Secrets Act on which it is based,” in R.C. Dreyfuss and K.J. Strandburg (eds.),
The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of Contemporary Research, Edward
Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Sanger, D. & N. Perlroth (2013), “Chinese Hackers Resume Attacks on U.S. Targets,” New York
Times, A1, 19 May, available as of 13 August 2013 at:
http://www.nytimes.com/2013/05/20/world/asia/chinese-hackers-resume-attacks-on-ustargets.html?_r=0 .
Schacht, W.H. & J.R. Thomas (2011), Follow-On Biologics: The Law and Intellectual Property
Issues, Congressional Research Service, Washington, D.C.
Schultz, M.F. & D.C. Lippoldt (2014), “Approaches to Protection of Undisclosed Information
(Trade Secrets): Background Paper”, OECD Trade Policy Papers, No. 162, OECD Publishing.
doi: 10.1787/5jz9z43w0jnw-en.
Seyoum, B. (1993), “Property Rights Versus Public Welfare in the Protection of Trade Secrets In
Developing Countries,” International Trade Journal, 7.3, 341-360. More argumentative than
theoretical and empirical, it nevertheless contains some arguments regarding trade secrets’
impact on developing countries.
Sherby, E. (2004), A Primer on Commercial Litigation in Israel, available as of 13 August 2013 at:
http://www.sherby.co.il/Primer.pdf.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
166 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
* Sherwood, R.M. (1990), Intellectual Property and Economic Development, Westview Special
Studies in Science, Technology, and Public Policy. Excellent case studies regarding IP laws,
including trade secrets, in developing countries.
* Sichelman, T. & S.J.H. Graham (2010), “Patenting by Entrepreneurs: An Empirical Study,” 17
Michigan Telecommunications & Technology Law Review, 111, Analysis of entrepreneurs’
choices of patents vs. trade secrets.
Singh, H. (2010), “Protection of Trade Secrets through IP and Unfair Competition Law,” AIPPI
Report Q215.
Sirota, A (2011), “On contributing know-how in capital of Russian company,” available as of 14
August 2013 at: http://www.russianlawonline.com/content/contributing-know-how-capitalrussian-company.
Stankovic, M. (2010), “Trade Secrets: South Korea versus United States,” reference available as of
14 August 2013 at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1678768 .
Stouls, J.P. et al. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law,
AIPPI Report Q215, France.
Sumpter, P. (2006), Intellectual Property Law: Principles in Practice, CCH New Zealand, Auckland.
Toutoungi, A. (16 August 2012), “Trade Secrets Move (Slowly) Up the Agenda,” Eversheds
International Website,
http://www.eversheds.com/global/en/what/articles/index.page?ArticleID=en/Industrial_engine
ering/Trade_secrets_move-slowly-up_the_agenda.
US Department of State (March 2011), 2011 Investment Climate Statement – Republic of Korea,
http://www.state.gov/e/eb/rls/othr/ics/2011/157359.htm.
Ubukata, K. (2010), Question Q215: Protection of Trade Secrets Through IPR and Unfair
Competition Law, AIPPI Report on Japan.
UK Law Commission (1981), Report on Breach of Confidence, Law Com No.110.
UK Law Commission (1997), Misuse of Trade Secrets Consultation Paper, available as of 14 August
2013 at:
http://lawcommission.justice.gov.uk/docs/cp150_Legislating_the_Criminal_Code__Misuse_of_T
rade_Secrets_Consultation.pdf.
US National Science Foundation (2012), “Business Use of Intellectual Property Protection
Documented in NSF Survey,” NSF Infobrief 12‐307, National Center for Science and
Engineering Statistics.
USTR (2012), 2012 Special 301 Report, Office of the United States Trade Representative.
USTR (2007), 2007 Special 301 Report, Office of the U.S. Trade Representative.
Vaidyanathan, R.K. (2010), “Trade Secrets and Confidential Information,” Advaya Legal Law Firm
Website, September.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
167 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Vos, A. (2008), “South Africa: Discovery of Confidential Documents,” Mondaq.com, 13 November,
available as of 14 August 2013 at:
http://www.mondaq.com/x/69448/Discovery+Of+Confidential+Documents.
WTO (2012), Trade Policy Review Body – Report by the Secretariat – Israel, WT/TPR/S/272, 52
(25 September 2012), World Trade Organization.
Zabojnik, J. (2002), “A Theory of Trade Secrets in Firms,” International Economic Review, 43,
831-55.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
168 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
SELECTED LAWS AND PRECEDENT
This section lists the most significant statutes governing trade secrets in the jurisdictions conveyed.
In the case of common law jurisdictions with few or no statutes governing trade secrets, this listing
contains citations to significant cases.
Australia
Statutes
•
Australia Therapeutic Goods Act 1989
•
Agricultural and Veterinary Chemicals Code Act 1994
Cases
•
Coco v. A.N. Clark (Engineers) Ltd. [1969] RPC 41 (English law)
•
Franklin v. Giddins [1978] Qd R 72
•
Mainbridge Industries Pty. Ltd. v. Whitewood (1984) 73 FLR 117.
•
Moorgate Tobacco Co. Ltd. v. Philip Morris Ltd. (No. 2) (1984) 156 CLR 414
•
Searle Australia Pty. Ltd. v. Public Interest Advocacy Center & Anor (1992) 36 FCR 111
Brazil
Statutes
•
Article 195, Sections XI – XII Law No. 9.279 of May 14, 1996 (Industrial Property Law).
China
Statutes
•
Article 10, Unfair Competition Law of the People’s Republic of China (promulgated by the
Standing Comm. Nat’l People’s Cong., Sept. 2, 1993, effective Sept. 2, 1993
•
Article 22 of the Labour Law
•
Article 43 of the Contract Law
France
Statutes
•
Article L. 621-1 of the Intellectual Property Code
•
Article L. 1227-1 of the Labour Code
•
Article 1392 of the Civil Code
•
Article 226-13 of the Criminal Code
•
Article 311-1 of the Criminal Code
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
169 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
•
Article 314-1 of the Criminal Code
Germany
Statutes
•
Act Against Unfair Competition of 1909 (UWG)
India
Statutes
•
46th Report on the “Pesticide Management Bill, 2008,” Department Related Parliamentary
Standing Committee on Agriculture (2008)
Cases
•
AIA Engineering Pvt. Ltd. v. Bharat Dand and Ors., AIR 2007 Gujarat (NOC) 1456
•
Bank Ltd. v. Priya Puri, (2006) IIILLJ 540 Del.; Bombay Dyeing and Manufacturing Co. Ltd. v.
Mehar Karan Singh, 2010 (112) BomLR3759
•
Escorts Construction v. Action Construction, 1999 PTC 36 (Del)
•
Konrad Wiedemann GmbH v. Standard Castings Pvt. Ltd., [1985](10) IPLR 243; Mr. Diljeet
Saltman Engineering Co. v. Campbell Engineering Co. Ltd., [1948] 65 RPC 203 (English law)
•
Titus, Advocate v. Mr. Alfred A. Adebare and Ors., 2006 (32) PTC 609 (Del); American
Express
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
170 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
Israel
Statutes
•
Commercial Torts Law, Section 5, Israel - Unfair Competition (Commercial Torts). World
Intellectual Property Organization, Law, 19/04/1999 -5759(il012), Available at:
http://www.wipo.int/clea/docs_new/pdf/en/il/il012en.pdf
Italy
Statutes
•
Legislative Decree No. 30 of 10 February 2005 and amended by Legislative Decree No. 131 of
13 August 2010, under the header "Secret information".
•
Article 99 IPC, as amended by Legislative Decree No. 131 of 13 August 2010.
•
Articles 621, 622 and 623 of the Italian Criminal Code.
•
Article 2598 of the Italian Civil Code.
Japan
Statutes
•
Article 1(6), Unfair Competition Prevention Act (Act No. 47 of 1993) (up to the revisions of Act
No. 62 of 2011 (Effective December 1, 2011)), unofficial translation available at
http://www.wipo.int/wipolex/en/text.jsp?file_id=254517.
New Zealand
Statutes
•
Section 230(2) of the Crimes Act 1961
Cases
•
AB Consol. Ltd. v. Europe Strength Food Co. Pty. Ltd., [1978] 2 NZLR 515
•
Aquaculture Corp. v. New Zealand Green Mussel Co. Ltd. (No. 1), (1985) 5 IPR 353
•
Coco v. A.N. Clark (Engineers) Ltd. [1969] RPC 41 (English law)
•
Fisher & Paykel Finance v Karum, [2012] NZHC 331
•
SSC&B: Lintas New Zealand Ltd. v. Murphy & Anor, (1986) 3 NZCLC 99,546
Republic of Korea
Statutes
•
Trade Secrets Act, Article 1, Para. 2.
Russia
Statutes
•
Civil Code Article 1465 (2011)
•
Civil Code Article 1466(2) (2011)
•
Civil Code Article 1467 (2011)
•
Civil Code Article 1472(2)(2) (2011)
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
171 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
•
Article 183(1), Criminal Code of the Russian Federation No. 63-FZ of June 13, 1996 (as last
amended on June 29, 2009)
•
Federal Law Commercial Secrecy, No. 98-FZ, Article 10 (July 29, 2004) (as amended July 24,
2007)
South Africa
Cases
•
Advtech Resourcing (Pty) Ltd v Kuhn 2007(4) ALL SA 1386 ,C para51
•
Bambelela Bolts (Pty) Ltd v Ball and Another (J 2977/11) [2012] ZALCJHB 148
•
Document Warehouse (Pty) Limited v Truebody and Another (2010/26977) [2010] ZAGPJHC
92 (13 October 2010)
•
Dun and Bradstreet (Pty) Ltd v SA Merchants Combined Credit Bureau (Cape) (Pty) Ltd.,
(1968) 1 SA 209
Sweden
Statutes
•
Act on the Protection of Trade Secrets (SFS 1990:409).
United Kingdom
Cases
•
Attorney General v. Guardian Newspapers Ltd. (No. 2), [1988] 3 All ER 545.
•
Coco v. A.N. Clark Eng'rs Ltd., [1969] RPC 41
•
Exchange Telegraph Co. Ltd. v. Central News Ltd., [1897] 2 Ch. 48Lansing Linde Ltd v Kerr,
[1991] 1 W.L.R. 251
•
Faccenda Chicken Ltd. v. Fowler, [1986] 1 All ER 617
•
House of Lords in Herbert Morris, Ltd. v. Saxelby, [1916] 1 AC 688
•
Mustad v. Allcock and Dosen, [1963] 3 All ER 416
•
Saltman Engineering Co. v. Campbell Engineering Co. Ltd. [1948] 65 RPC 203
United States
Statutes
•
Espionage Act of 1996, as amended: 18 USC § 1831 and § 1832
•
EPA Pesticide Registration Manual, Chapter 10 (2010),
•
www.epa.gov/pesticides/bluebook/chapter10.html
•
First Restatement of Torts § 737 (1939)
•
Uniform Trade Secrets Act Section 1, available at:
•
www.uniformlaws.org/shared/docs/trade%20secrets/utsa_final_85.pdf
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
172 | APPROACHES TO THE PROTECTION OF TRADE SECRETS
ANNEXES
Due to the annexes’ length, which extends to several hundred pages, interested readers are referred to the
original version of this chapter, which is an OECD Trade Policy Working Paper (Schultz & Lippoldt,
2014), available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jz9z43w0jnw-en.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
173 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
CHAPTER 4. AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS
OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
In this chapter, the indicator developed in Chapter 3 is used to assess the economic implications of
variations in the stringency of protection in a larger sample of economies over an expanded time
horizon. The assessment is based on dual approaches, one qualitative and one quantitative. This
work – the first of its kind ever to be carried out with respect to trade secrets – delivers new
insights on the importance of trade secrets protection to economic performance, including
innovation and growth. Most importantly, the assessment leads to the finding that the stringency of
trade secrets protection is positively related to indicators of innovation. The work also shows that
the stringency of trade secrets protection grew substantially in the sample economies between 1985
and 2010.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities or third
party. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and
Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
It should be noted that statistical data on Israeli patents and trademarks are supplied by the patent and trademark
offices of the relevant countries.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
174 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
ABSTRACT
This chapter takes stock of the protection of trade secrets for a sample of 37 countries, provides
historical data for the period since 1985, and considers the relationship of the stringency of the protection
of trade secrets to relevant economic performance indicators. The chapter finds that there has been a
notable increase in the stringency of trade secrets protection in a broad sample of countries during the
period from 1985 to 2010. The chapter also finds a positive association between the stringency of trade
secrets protection and key indicators of innovation and international economic flows. Further details of the
methodology and additional country data can be found in the original version of chapter 3, which is an
OECD Trade Policy Working Paper, available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jz9z43w0jnw-en.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
175 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
This chapter takes stock of the protection of trade secrets for a sample of 37 countries, provides
historical data for the period since 1985, and considers the relationship of the stringency of the protection
of trade secrets to relevant economic performance indicators. The chapter is structured around two main
approaches: a qualitative assessment of relevant economic performance issues drawing on the literature
and a quantitative assessment of the relationship between the Trade Secrets Protection Index and indicators
of economic performance. The study employs the methodology for assessment of the stringency of trade
secrets protection that was developed in chapter 3.
The assessment of the stringency of trade secrets protection across a broad sample of countries in
recent decades found substantial variation between countries at specific points in time and in protection
regimes of specific countries over time. The qualitative assessment then considered a number of potential
areas where variation in trade secrets protection could influence economic performance. These included
economic incentives for innovation, labour mobility, spillover effects and technological diffusion. The
empirical assessment found that the stringency of protection in the developed countries rose in particular
during the 1990s and then stabilised, while developing countries on average tended to rise throughout the
entire study period. The quantitative assessment of the relationship of this increased stringency of
protection to indicators of economic performance found a tendency for there to be a positive relationship.
This includes indicators of innovation inputs and international economic flows of investment and trade.
Through such relationships, trade secrets protection may have implications for developments in domestic
innovation, international technology transfer and access to technology-intensive inputs and related
products.
These findings represent a first step in the assessment of trade secrets protection. However, it should
be noted that the relationships highlighted here reflect association but not necessarily causality. It is also
necessary to note that the relationships identified in the empirical assessment apply to a specific sample
during a specific time period and a certain range of variation. This does not mean that ever stronger
protection, for example, will yield similar results. Nonetheless, the positive and statistically significant
relationships identified do provide an indication that provision of adequate protection of trade secrets may
be an appropriate element of a policy framework supporting certain key aspects of economic performance.
Further research could contribute to confirming these findings and exploring the effects of trade secrets
protection at sectoral and firm level.
Introduction
This chapter takes stock of the protection of trade secrets for a sample of 37 countries, provides
historical data for the period since 1985, and considers the relationship of the stringency of the protection
of trade secrets to relevant economic performance indicators. The paper is structured around two main
approaches: a qualitative assessment of relevant economic performance issues drawing on the literature
and a quantitative assessment of the relationship between the Trade Secrets Protection Index and indicators
of economic performance. The study employs the methodology for assessment of the stringency of trade
secrets protection that was developed in chapter 3. The chapter begins with an overview of the
international framework for protection of trade secrets. It then provides sections treating each of the main
themes in turn. The conclusions highlight policy relevant findings with respect to the implications of the
stringency of protection available for trade secrets.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
176 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Overview: International Framework for Protection of Trade Secrets
The World Trade Organisation’s (WTO) Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual
Property Rights (TRIPS) Agreement was the first multilateral agreement to directly address trade secrets
protection (Box 4.1.). The approach laid out in the TRIPS Agreement is based on the notion that protection
against unfair competition should include protection for undisclosed information 116. In presenting this
approach, the TRIPS Agreement makes reference to the prior-existing protection against unfair
competition as presented in the Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property (1967), a
convention that is administered by the World Intellectual Property Organization 117.
Guided by the provisions of Article 39 of the TRIPS agreement, the definition of trade secrets has
tended to converge across the countries considered in this assessment. As noted in Chapter 3, definitions
generally recognise a trade secret as information that is secret, has commercial value as a result, and is
subject to reasonable efforts to maintain the secrecy. The concepts tend to be applied as follows:
• Secrecy. The information protected must actually be secret. Secrecy need not be absolute.
Secrecy requires that the information must not be readily publically accessible and that it is
revealed to others only under conditions that maintain secrecy with respect to the broader
public 118.Thus, the trade secret owner may share the information with employees and
business partners.
• Commercial Value. The information must have economic value as a result of its being secret
and must derive some utility from being kept secret.
• Reasonable Efforts to Maintain Secrecy. The information must be the subject of reasonable
efforts on the part of the rights holder to maintain its secrecy. By its nature, a trade secret
claim arises when measures to protect the secret have failed. Thus, the law tends not to
require one who claims a trade secret to be entirely successful at protecting it. In national
laws, the necessary effort is often broadly described as “reasonable,” in keeping with
Article 39 of TRIPS 119.
Here is it important to note that trade secrecy does not provide an exclusive right to use of the
information, provided that the second party obtains the information fairly or it enters the public domain by
fair means. Thus, unlike patented inventions or copyright protected content, trade secrets are not protected
for a statutory time limit and they can run out in the regular course of competition.
The scope of trade secret protection varies somewhat by country, but broadly concerns three
categories of information: 1) technical information; 2) confidential business information; and 3) knowhow. Technical information typically includes industrial processes, blueprints, formulae and similar
information regarding technology. Confidential business information typically includes customer lists (in
cases where they include truly non-public information), financial information, business plans and similar
information regarding the operation of a business. Know-how includes information about methods, steps
and processes for achieving efficient results. Most countries recognise the first two categories, often
without differentiating them. Know-how is a term commonly used both in discussion of proprietary
information and in agreements, but it enjoys less formal recognition as a separate, defined category of trade
secrets.
As can be seen from Box 4.1., the TRIPS Agreement does not provide much guidance on the specifics
of the national systems to be put in place to protect trade secrets. Consequently, countries employ a broad
range of means to provide the TRIPS-mandated protection. In some instances, countries have implemented
express legislation. In others, the obligation is met by laws that include misappropriation via such means as
breach of contract, inducement of others to breach contracts and acquisition by third parties of information
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
177 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
known to be disclosed dishonestly or where it was negligent not to know. This variation in means can
affect the ways businesses and workers conduct their affairs and thus there are reasons to believe that the
legal protection of trade secrets may have important economic effects.
Box 4.1. The TRIPS Agreement on Undisclosed Information
Protection of undisclosed information is addressed in Article 39 of the Agreement on Trade-Related
Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) of the World Trade Organization (WTO). This agreement
entered into force on 1 January 1995 and established an international standard requiring WTO Members to
protect undisclosed information including agricultural and pharmaceutical test data.
__________________
Section 7: Protection of Undisclosed Information, Article 39
[of the TRIPS Agreement]
1. In the course of ensuring effective protection against unfair competition as provided in Article 10bis
of the Paris Convention (1967), Members shall protect undisclosed information in accordance with
paragraph 2 and data submitted to governments or governmental agencies in accordance with
1
paragraph 3.
2. Natural and legal persons shall have the possibility of preventing information lawfully within their
control from being disclosed to, acquired by, or used by others without their consent in a manner contrary
2
to honest commercial practices so long as such information:
(a) is secret in the sense that it is not, as a body or in the precise configuration and assembly of
its components, generally known among or readily accessible to persons within the circles
that normally deal with the kind of information in question;
(b)
has commercial value because it is secret; and
(c) has been subject to reasonable steps under the circumstances, by the person lawfully in
control of the information, to keep it secret.
3. Members, when requiring, as a condition of approving the marketing of pharmaceutical or of
agricultural chemical products which utilize new chemical entities, the submission of undisclosed test or
other data, the origination of which involves a considerable effort, shall protect such data against unfair
commercial use. In addition, Members shall protect such data against disclosure, except where necessary
to protect the public, or unless steps are taken to ensure that the data are protected against unfair
commercial use.
Footnotes:
1. These paragraph references refer to paragraphs 2 and 3 of Article 39 of the TRIPS Agreement.
2. At this point in the original text, there is a footnote, numbered 10, that states:
For the purpose of this provision, “a manner contrary to honest commercial practices” shall mean
at least practices such as breach of contract, breach of confidence and inducement to breach, and
includes the acquisition of undisclosed information by third parties who knew, or were grossly
negligent in failing to know, that such practices were involved in the acquisition.
Source: Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS), WTO.
Qualitative Assessment
This qualitative assessment is based on key themes emerging from the economic and business
literature and available statistics on the issue of trade secrets protection. It describes the theoretical and
perceived role of trade secrets in economic performance and innovation. Information on firm-level impacts
is included, including with respect to small and medium size firms (SMEs) and start-ups. The relationship
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
178 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
to national economic development is also considered. The evidence highlights the value of trade secrets, as
well as the scope and nature of trade secret theft and misappropriation among competing firms.
Previous theoretical work points to several ways in which trade secret protection may incentivise
investment in research and development (R&D) as well as the creation of commercially valuable
information. First, such protection may increase the appropriability of the results from investment in the
development of technical and confidential business information. It does this by deterring employees,
business partners and third parties from misappropriating or misusing specific information meeting the
trade secrets criteria. Kitch (1980) views this benefit in terms of reducing the risk of theft, while Friedman
et al. (1991) emphasise that there is a reduction in the cost of protection in cases where the avenues of legal
recourse are clear and effective (i.e. in the absence of such legal protection firms may need to invest more
heavily in security measures). In either case, there is a potential for increased returns from R&D
investment, and thus such innovation may be incentivised.
A further incentivising effect noted in the literature is the role that trade secrets may play in conferring
competitive benefits. Lemley (2011) observes that firms may invest in developing trade secrets because the
prospect of supra-competitive profits motivates them to do so. In this view, a trade secret may confer a
competitive advantage through a production process that reduces cost or delivers a unique product. In
addition, incentives may be associated with trade secrets as an alternative or complementary protection to
patents. In cases where patents are legally unavailable, too expensive to maintain, or undesirable due to
their disclosure requirement, Maskus (2000) and Friedman et al. (1991) argue that trade secrets can
substitute for patents and provide incentives to innovate. Trade secrets can also provide protection during
the developmental phase leading to a patent (i.e. prior to a formal patent application). In some cases
(e.g. due to the immediate availability or potentially low costs), firms may even employ trade secrets as
their preferred strategy for protection of their intangible assets (e.g. see Arundel, 2001, or Cohen et al.,
2000).
On the other hand, in cases of weak protection for trade secrets, there could be more spillovers of
R&D information amongst competitors. Such information may stimulate investment by firms in further
internal R&D to complement the incoming information or to gain a first mover advantage. For example, a
firm may need to have sufficient internal R&D to make use of external R&D, and vice versa (Lokshin
et al., 2006). Weak appropriability could drive firms to pursue R&D in competitive races to develop
products, relying on first mover advantage, temporary secrecy, or patents to secure an edge 120. While this is
a theoretical possibility, there are some indications that relatively stringent trade secrets protection may
actually deliver an increased sharing of information among potential collaborators, as businesses are
reassured that they can enforce their rights in the event of a breach of trust or misappropriation (Lemley,
2011). This potential was highlighted in a recent study commissioned by the European Commission (Baker
& McKenzie, 2013), which included a survey of firms’ use of trade secrets. The survey found that while
60% of businesses share their trade secrets regularly or occasionally, among those that declined to share
such information 40% cited fear of loss of confidentiality as the reason. Moreover, even in countries with
relatively stringent trade secrets protection, there are usually exemptions or limitations on the definition
and scope of trade secrecy that permit spillovers of general knowledge, skills and experience.
The availability of trade secrets protection may influence firms’ size and structure, as well their
engagement in the labour market. If trade secrets protection is less stringent, then firms that depend on
critical non-public information may be less willing to expand, as secrets are kept within a trusted circle
(e.g. some family businesses). In such an environment, firms may be less willing to outsource
manufacturing or to engage in joint ventures. Labour market implications are further highlighted via two
studies of the United States (Png, 2012a and 2012b). He found that some US states enacting increased
trade secret protection may have experienced relatively modest declines in the mobility of postgraduate
engineers and scientists (e.g. due to enforcement of contractual requirements concerning non-competition);
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
179 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
this in turn might slow the pace of spillover effects. However, Png (2012b) found that enactment of a trade
secret law in US states was associated with a significant increase in R&D spending. Other studies point to
implications for spillovers in that less stringent trade secrets protection may cause firms to attempt to retain
employees by attempting to prevent employee movement by paying employees wage premia or hiring
relatives (Sherwood, 1990). More stringent trade secret protection may also impede employee mobility by:
(a) enforcing non-compete provisions 121 or (b) imposing confidentiality obligations on ex-employees that
make them less valuable to new employers 122.
There are some indications that innovative small and medium size enterprises (SMEs) may be
particularly reliant on trade secrecy as protection for their intellectual assets (Brant and Lohse, 2013).
Subject to reasonable efforts on the part of such firms to maintain the required secrecy, in many
jurisdictions trade secrets protection is readily available without burdensome administrative requirements
and in some cases may be maintained at comparatively low cost123. While patents may be appropriate for
protecting some types of intellectual property – as in cases where a new technology is readily discerned by
competitors upon the release of a product into the market, they can also be more costly in terms of time and
resources 124. For example, in addition to filing and maintenance fees and administrative requirements,
patenting may expose SMEs to risks of litigation (Lanjouw and Schankerman, 2004) 125. Thus, in cases
where trade secrets protection is adequate and appropriate, its use may prove advantageous for certain
SMEs.
The availability of trade secrets protection may also play a role in international diffusion of
technologies and other information via foreign direct investment (FDI) or trade. Firms may be more likely
to invest or trade in a country that protects trade secrets, particularly where that investment requires the
business to reveal or develop trade secrets (e.g. in cases where tacit knowledge is employed in the
implementation of patent-protected processes). In entering a market, firms face a choice of engaging a
local partner or starting a subsidiary. The stringency of trade secret protection may affect this choice by
making a firm more or less willing to share product information and sales techniques with a local partner
(CREATe, 2012). In the literature on intellectual property rights (IPR) protection and FDI, there is some
evidence that firms respond positively to availability of such IPR protection (e.g. Park and Lippoldt, 2008).
In addition, firms in different sectors or employing different technologies may respond differently to the
availability of particular types of protection. Thus, trade secrets protection may have economy-wide effects
as well as sector or technology-specific effects in relation to FDI or trade.
In terms of the interaction with alternative forms of intellectual property rights, there is a clear
potential relationship to patent protection. As noted above, firms that depend on patent protection may tend
to rely on trade secrets protection during the developmental stage of the technology (Png, 2012a).
However, in some specific cases of technological innovation, firms may forgo patent protection entirely
and rely exclusively on trade secrets protection. For example, this may be the case with process innovation
where the resulting product is difficult to reverse engineer. The effect may depend on practical aspects of
protection under each form of protection 126. As a legal matter, not all inventions or information that can be
kept secret are patentable. In terms of release of a product on the market, not all patentable aspects of the
innovations that it may embody can be kept secret, which is a requirement for trade secret protection.
Getting a handle empirically on the effects of trade secret protection is challenging due to the very
nature of trade secrets as being secret by definition. In addition, firms are reluctant to report trade secret
theft. Even where there are legal actions, the civil litigation and criminal prosecution rates could have a
variety of meanings. A lack of litigation could mean that the law is effectively deterring abuses or that
trade secret owners or prosecutors view the law as ineffective and legal action as futile. Similarly, high
rates of litigation could signal widespread disrespect for the law by defendants or confidence on the part of
plaintiffs and prosecutors. In order to take a step towards untangling the economic implications of such
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
180 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
issues, the quantitative assessment that follows will consider the relationship between the stringency of
trade secrets protection and certain key economic indicators.
In light of the costs of continued abuse of trade secrets, a number of OECD Members have initiatives
underway to address concerns about uncertainty or gaps in protection. With respect to some dimensions of
protection, these initiatives seek to harmonise and develop minimum standards. For some stakeholders, the
motivation for such reforms is a goal of reducing the complexity of managing trade secrets protection
across international boundaries and promoting market opening effects in cases where businesses are
currently precluded entry due to vulnerability of their operations to trade secrets abuse 127. Two notable
efforts currently underway concern the European Union and the United States. In the case of the European
Union, the European Commission launched in November 2013 a draft directive intended to help harmonise
key aspects of civil law protection across the EU Member countries. The directive would provide for a
common definition of trade secrets; means through which victims of trade secret misappropriation could
obtain redress (e.g. offering protection of secrecy during court proceedings); and remedies (e.g. damages,
recall and destruction of infringing products, and availability of injunctions) 128. In 2013, the United States
released the “Administration Strategy on Mitigating the Theft of US Trade Secrets”, which included a set
of action items for improved protection domestically and internationally 129. Among other actions, the
strategy would promote prosecution of abuses 130, development of industry-led best practices, review of
laws, diplomatic engagement and public awareness.
Trade Secrets Protection Index
Index Composition
In order to measure the extent of the variation in stringency of available protection for trade secrets,
the Trade Secrets Protection Index (TSPI) was developed in Chapter 3. Chart 4.1. presents the detailed
composition of the index and its scoring. The index is structured around five main components:
1.
Definitions and coverage
2.
Specific duties and misappropriation
3.
Remedies and restrictions on liability
4.
Enforcement, investigation & discovery; data exclusivity
5.
System functioning and related regulation.
The approach to scoring provides up to one point for each of the five main components of the index
and a maximum total score for the index of five points. However, as can be seen in Chart 4.1., the number
of elements covered by each of the main components of the index varies widely. For example, the
definition and coverage of trade secrets protection comprises 13 elements, whereas the system functioning
and related regulation comprises 4 elements. In order to maintain balance across the five components of the
index, the scoring for the various elements under each of the five main components was normalised to
ensure equal weighting. In other words, the elements for each main component add up to a maximum score
of one 131. Overall, the index is designed to capture information on the stringency of the available protection
in a manner that is internationally comparable 132.
As noted in Chapter 3, the TSPI is designed with several considerations in mind. First, the five
components represent key aspects of protection of trade secrets where there is some variation across
countries that may influence the stringency of protection. As part of an initial survey, its scope is
intentionally very broad. Second, the elements of the TSPI were structured to enable scoring based
primarily on objective criteria, supplemented in some cases by qualitative information as necessary (e.g. in
certain areas related to system operation). Third, in order to ensure coherence across the components, the
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
181 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
index employs an integrated index approach rather than separate indicators. Fourth, the presentation of the
index emphasises transparency, with scores supported by a text chart for each country and verifiable
references. Fifth, the index is designed to provide an indication of the stringency of available protection; it
aims to be neutral in this assessment. In other words, a higher or low score reflects the strength of
protection and not an assessment of the appropriate level of protection. While the TSPI measures
stringency, it does not provide an indication of what level of stringency is optimal. (Policy makers will
need to determine the appropriate level of protection taking into account their local institutions and
conditions 133) The index’s function is descriptive, not normative, and the scores it produces are thus neither
grades nor ratings. Rather, the score is strictly a measure of stringency of protection. As a measurement
tool, the TSPI simply measures its target subjects.
TSPI Survey of Countries: Results for an Expanded Sample
For the economic assessment, the TSPI sample has been expanded from the original edition in
Chapter 3 to cover sixteen additional countries drawn from around the world, including developed and
developing countries 134. The detailed scoring for each element of the TSPI for all of the countries in the
sample can be found in the Annex Table. In addition, a presentation of the framework for trade secrets
protection in each of the countries newly added to the sample can be found in the Annex Chart, as can an
updated entry for New Zealand 135. (Charts covering each of the countries in the original sample can be
found in Chapter 3, Annex.) The sample has also been deepened to include a time dimension. Depending
on data availability, each country’s situation is measured at five year intervals starting as early as
1985 136.As of 2010, the countries in the sample are all members of the WTO and subject to the provisions
of the TRIPS Agreement.
For the year 2010, the expanded sample has a profile that is similar to the original sample as described
in Chapter 3. The scores in the expanded sample range from 2.5 to 4.5 points, with a median of 3.6
(Table 4.1.) 137. Despite the significant gap between the high and low scores, the overall dispersion of the
scores is fairly modest. The sample was also tested for the impact of two alternative weighting schemes,
one giving double weighting to enforcement, investigation, discovery and data exclusivity, and another
giving double weighting to remedies and restrictions on liabilities. These alternate weighting schemes did
not alter the country rankings significantly as can be seen from the Spearman Rank Correlation
coefficients. Thus, by this standard, the TSPI with equal weights appears to be a robust indicator for the
relative underlying trade secret protection.
In Figure 4.1., the country rankings for the TSPI can be seen as of 2010, ranging from a high score in
the United States to a low score for the Philippines. The OECD countries tend to have higher rankings in
the table than the partner countries. In 2010, all of the countries have TSPI scores of 3 or above, with the
exception of Bulgaria, India, the People’s Republic of China, Indonesia, Russia and the Philippines.
Table 4.2. and Figure 4.1. present the composition of the TSPI scores for each country in the sample as of
2010. The area of duties and misappropriation has the highest average scores and shows a fairly high
degree of alignment. The areas of enforcement, investigation and discovery; data exclusivity and system
functioning and related regulation have the lowest average scores, with wide variation in the scores and
particular weakness in a few developing and transition economies.
The evolution of the TSPI over time is presented in Figure 4.2. and Table 4.3. As can be seen from the
Table, the overall average score increased incrementally in each period. The Figure highlights an important
perspective on the composition of these changes. There is a significant gap between the scores of the
OECD and the trade partner countries in the sample. Over time this gap has closed somewhat, but remains
significant. The OECD scores gradually rose before stabilising during 2005 and 2010. Figure 4.2 reflects
substantial increases in the average partner country scores in the period following the entry into force of
the TRIPS Agreement. Figure 4.3. presents the evolution over time, by economy and year. From this visual
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
182 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
perspective, notable strengthening – here defined as sustained changes of greater than one point from 1990
to 2010 – can be readily seen for economies such as Brazil, China, Korea, Mexico, Spain, Chinese Taipei,
and Thailand. In addition, certain transition economies demonstrated notable increases in their scores
during the period since 1995 including Lithuania and the Russian Federation. In the cases of China and
Russia, their accession to the WTO may have played a role in promoting availability of more stringent
protection for trade secrets over the past decade. Analytically, the availability of the multiple observations
for each economy permits assessment of the relationship of increased stringency of trade secrets protection
to relevant indicators of economic performance over time, an issue discussed in the next section of the
chapter.
Figure 4.4. presents two illustrative scatter plots for the full pooled sample to highlight the basic
relationship of the TSPI to two key variables for economic performance. The first is real R&D per capita
(Panel A) and the second is real foreign technological services (Panel B, shown with the variables as
natural logarithms). For each economy and time period, each point in the charts represents the TSPI score
and the level for the variable of interest. As indicated by the upward sloping trend lines, the patterns in
each panel provide an indication of a simple positive correlation between TSPI stringency and the variables
of interest. The trendline in Panel A accounts for about a quarter of the variation in the plot and the trend
line in Panel B accounts for about one-fifth of the variation in the plot. However, a more rigorous
examination of the data, controlling for other factors, is required to obtain a robust assessment. This is the
object of the next section.
Quantitative Assessment
Maskus (2000), Primo Braga (1990) and others have noted that economic theory is inconclusive on
the expected outcomes from a strengthening of intellectual property rights; empirical analysis is required to
complement the theoretical perspectives. A strengthening of rights may promote market expansion effects
as rights holders are better able to leverage their intellectual property. Thus, such reforms may motivate
stakeholders to increase innovation and access to innovation in a manner that tends to benefit users as well
as producers of intellectual property. However, reforms could in theory increase the market power of rights
holders such that they have an incentive to constrain access and exploit their existing stock of innovation,
possibly with little economic benefit to society as a whole.
Similarly with respect to trade secrets, one might expect improved protection of trade secrets to
improve the ability of the owners to appropriate economic benefits from their secrets. However, the
incentives for further innovation, exploitation and diffusion of new trade secrets could in theory be
diminished somewhat by a strengthened availability of protection for existing trade secrets (despite their
fragility). Consequently, empirical analysis can play an important role in assessment of trade secrets
reforms. It is needed in order to test the hypothesis that greater stringency of protection contributes to
increased innovation and diffusion of trade secrets. Due to lack of data availability, the quantitative
empirical assessment presented below does not look at these market effects directly, but rather it considers
the associated net changes in economic indicators at an aggregate level while controlling for other factors.
Thus, building on the expanded TSPI sample, the following quantitative assessment considers
variation in trade secret protection in relation to an illustrative set of relevant economic performance
indicators. The modelling is based on standard regression analysis, using an approach similar to that
employed in previous OECD studies on economic implications of the strengthening of IPR
protection 138.The selection of economic indicators emphasises types of activity where effective protection
of trade secrets may be reasonably hypothesised to play a role in promoting expanded activity. Where
regression analysis is pursued, particular attention is focused on issues of auto-correlation and of
endogeneity 139.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
183 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Methodological approach
The quantitative assessment explores empirically the potential relationships identified in the
qualitative assessment. It considers these in a dynamic fashion using pooled regression analysis for the
period from 1990 to 2010, though a number of assessments cover shorter time periods due to data
limitations. The sample is an unbalanced panel in that the sample does not cover every country for every
year. Due to indications of autocorrelation in the residuals (low Durbin-Watson test scores), the regressions
were run using country fixed effects 140. As feasible, all variables were entered as natural logarithms, with
the result that the coefficients indicate the relationships in approximate percentage terms.
The regressions were set up using a standard linear regression model 141:
ln (economic performance indicatorn,t) = α0 + α1 ln (TSPI n,t) + α2 ln (Z n,t) + Error term
where n is country, t is time (year), and Z represents the control variables.
In all cases, the independent variable of interest is the TSPI. The dependent economic performance
indicators of interest covered innovation inputs (R&D expenditure, researchers in R&D) and
innovation-related international economic performance (real FDI inflows, total services imports, real
technological services imports, and real merchandise imports). The control variables were selected based
on indications of potential competing influences vis-à-vis trade secrets protection and include indicators of
market openness and regulation, market size, income level, and human capital development. The protection
of patent rights was considered as measured by the Park-Ginarte Patent Rights Index. The patent rights
index is constructed in a manner similar to that of the TSPI 142; details of its composition are presented in
Chart 3. Chart 4 provides an overview of the underlying data sources for the variables.
In order to illustrate various relationships, the regression runs presented employ fairly diverse
approaches. In the first run, the TSPI variable was lagged in order to test for endogeneity. In the second
run, it was interacted with the Patent Rights Index to observe whether the combined indicator also
exhibited a significant association with an indicator of economic performance. In the area of services, the
two runs were implemented using first differences approaches. This was done to provide an indication as to
whether change in the TSPI stringency over time affected the pace of change in imports in the sector.
Results
The results of the quantitative economic assessment are shown in Table 4.4 and Figure 4.5. The
assessment begins with consideration of the relationship of trade secrets protection to R&D activity and
then turns to international economic flows.
Table 4.4., parts (1) and (2), consider two aspects of the relationship of stringency of trade secrets
protection to real economy-wide R&D expenditure (government and business) per capita 143 and R&D
intensity as measured by R&D personnel as a share of the labour force. A positive and statistically
significant relationship is found between trade secrets protection (lagged one period) and the indicator for
R&D expenditure 144. A similar – though slightly larger – association is found between the combined
TSPI-patent rights indicator and R&D personnel as a share of the labour force. Among the control
variables, GDP and GDP per capita, respectively, are statistically highly significant in each of the runs.
Table 4.4., part (3), examines the relationship of real FDI inflows to TSPI, finding a particularly strong and
positive association. A one percent change in the TSPI is associated with a nearly 1.5% change in Real FDI
inflows (Figure 4.5.). Several control variables proved to be significant as well in this run, including GDP
(market size), market regulation, and the share of the labour force with tertiary education.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
184 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Table 4.4., parts (4), (5) and (6), considers the relationship of trade flows to the stringency of trade
secret protection. In all three cases the relationships were positive. For total services imports and foreign
technological services, the relationship was stronger with respect to the change in pace (first differences)
than to the simple flows. In other words, an increase in the stringency of trade secrets protection was
associated with an increase in the rate of growth of services imports for the sample economies during this
time period. This effect was particularly evident with respect to imports of foreign technological services.
Among the control variables, GDP per capita and GDP, respectively, were positive and significant.
Table 4.4., part (6) considers the relationship of TSPI stringency to real merchandise import flows. Here as
well a positive and statistically significant relationship was found.
Overall, this initial round of exploration of the economic implications found a positive and
statistically significant relationship between the increased stringency of trade secrets protection and
indicators for innovation inputs and international economic flows. FDI inflows and real foreign
technological services imports appear to be particularly sensitive to the stringency of trade secrets
protection. The strength and consistency of the results across the various analytical approaches lends
support to the hypothesis of a positive and fairly robust relationship of the TSPI to the types of economic
performance considered here, at least with respect to the sampled economies and timeframe 145.
Conclusions
This assessment of the stringency of trade secrets protection across a broad sample of countries in
recent decades found substantial variation between countries at specific points in time and in protection
regimes of specific countries over time. The qualitative assessment then considered a number of potential
areas where variation in trade secrets protection could influence economic performance. These included
economic incentives for innovation, labour mobility, spillover effects and technological diffusion. The
empirical assessment found that the stringency of protection in the developed countries rose in particular
during the 1990s and then stabilised, while developing countries on average tended to rise throughout the
entire study period. The quantitative assessment of the relationship of this increased stringency of
protection to indicators of economic performance found a tendency for there to be a positive relationship.
This includes indicators of innovation inputs and international economic flows of investment and trade.
Through such relationships, trade secrets protection may have positive implications for developments in
domestic innovation, international technology transfer and access to technology-intensive inputs and
related products.
These findings represent a first step in the assessment of trade secrets protection. However, it should
be noted that the relationships highlighted here reflect association but not necessarily causality. It is also
necessary to note that the relationships identified in the empirical assessment apply to a specific sample
during a specific time period and a certain range of variation. This does not mean that ever stronger
protection, for example, will yield similar results. Thus, care is required in the interpretation of the results.
Nonetheless, the positive and statistically significant relationships identified do provide an indication that
provision of adequate protection of trade secrets may be an appropriate element of a policy framework
supporting certain key aspects of economic performance. Further research could contribute to confirming
these findings and exploring the effects of trade secrets protection at sectoral and firm level 146.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
185 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
CHARTS, TABLES AND FIGURES
Chart 4.1.
Trade Secrets Protection Index
Components and scoring
Score range
1. Definition and Coverage
0-13
Normalised score
0-1
a) Scope
•
If scope covers all confidential business information, subject
to: 1) deriving value from secrecy and 2) the owner’s
reasonable efforts to maintain secrecy, score = 1; If scope
also subject to requirement that information is imparted to
the recipient in confidence, score = ½
0, 1
b) Additional Elements of Definition
•
Inventory of trade secrets required (requirement=0; no
requirement=1)
0, 1
•
Must be reduced
requirement=1)
no
0, 1
•
Must be identified as a trade
(requirement=0; no requirement=1)
recipient
0, 1
•
Written notice to recipient required (requirement=0; no
requirement=1)
0, 1
to
writing
(requirement=0;
secret
to
c) Acts covered as civil infringement:
•
Breach of duty (not covered=0, partially covered=½ 147,
covered=1)
Wrongful acquisition or misappropriation (not covered=0,
covered=1)
0, 1
•
Third party liability for acquisition with knowledge or reason
to know (not available=0, available=1)
0, 1
•
Third party liability for acquisition without knowledge - enjoin
“innocent parties” (not available=0, available=1)
0, 1
•
0, 1
d) Acts covered by criminal law
•
Breach of duty (not covered=0, partially covered=½,
covered=1)
Wrongful acquisition or misappropriation (not covered=0,
covered=1)
0, 1
•
Third party liability for acquisition with knowledge or reason
to know (not available=0, available=1)
0, 1
•
Third party liability for acquisition without knowledge, enjoin
“innocent parties” (not available=0, available=1)
0, 1
•
0, 1
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
186 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Chart 4.1.
Trade Secrets Protection Index (continued)
Components and scoring
Score range
2. Specific duties and misappropriation 148
•
Commercial relationship (covered if arising from: express
agreement ½ + implied duty ½)
0, 1
•
Current employment relationship (covered if arising from:
express agreement ½ + implied duty ½)
0, 1
•
Past employment relationship (covered if arising from:
express agreement ½ + implied duty ½)
0, 1
•
Restrictions on post-relationship duty of confidentiality (if
any restrictions on matters beyond general skills and
knowledge, by relationship: commercial ½ + employment ½)
0, 1
•
Validity of contractual restrictions on competition (if
unenforceable=0, significant limitations=½ (e.g., limited by
time or place for either commercial or post-employment
situations), generally enforceable=1)
0, 1
3. Remedies and Restrictions on liability
a) Restrictions on liability
•
Additional elements of proof in infringement claims (if none:
civil=½ + criminal=½, criminal ½ point; score 1 if there no
criminal law and civil score is ½)
0, 1
b) Civil remedies
•
•
Preliminary injunction (if available = 1, if not = 0)
Ex parte action available under preliminary injunction (if
available = 1, if not = 0)
0, 1
0, 1
•
•
Permanent injunction (if available = 1, if not = 0)
Injunction to eliminate wrongful head start (if available = 1,
if not = 0)
0, 1
0, 1
•
Delivery or destruction of infringing materials (if available =
1, if not = 0)
0, 1
•
Compensatory damages (direct or out of pocket damages or
consideration of profits or other damages= 1)
0, 1
•
Yielding of defendant’s profits (if available = 1, if not = 0)
0, 1
•
Availability of punitive or statutory damages (if available =
1, if not = 0)
0, 1
c) Criminal remedies
•
Fines, damages or loss of assets (if not available = 0, if
minimal per expert opinion= ½, if substantial = 1)
0, 1
•
Jail sentence (if available = 1, if not = 0)
0, 1
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
Normalised score
0-5
0-1
0-11
0-1
187 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Chart 4.1..
Trade Secrets Protection Index (continued)
Components and scoring
Score range
4. Enforcement, investigation and discovery;
data exclusivity
a) Enforcement, investigation and discovery
•
Emergency search to preserve and obtain proof
(unavailable=0, available but with significant restrictions= ½
(e.g., conducted solely by an official or 3rd party expert),
readily available=1)
0, 1
•
Ex parte emergency search availability (unavailable=0,
available but with significant restrictions=½, readily
available=1)
0, 1
•
Pre-trial discovery (unavailable=0, documentary only or
strict limitations = ½, ready availability of documentary and
interrogatories = 1)
0, 1
•
Protection of confidentiality of trade secrets in litigation
(none=0, partial= ½, fully available=1)
0, 1
Normalised score
0-6
0-1
0-4
0-1
b) Data exclusivity
•
•
Drugs (years: 0=0; 0.1-3=1/3; 3.1-7.9=2/3; >8=1)
Agricultural chemicals (years: 0=0, 0.1-4.9=1/3, 5-8=2/3; >
8=1)
0, 1
0, 1
5. System functioning and related regulation
•
Technology transfer: registration requirement (none=1; one
or more = 0)
0, 1
•
Technology transfer: substantive review or regulation
(none=1; one or more = 0)
0, 1
•
Fraser Institute score for Legal System and Security of
Property Rights (score ranging from 0 to 10, divided by
10) 149
Expert characterisation of the operation of the protection in
practice (NB, based on internationally recognised or peerreviewed sources; see country charts for details)
(Negative = 0; none = ½; positive = 1)
0, 1
•
Index Total
0, 1
======
0-5
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
188 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Chart 4.2.
Trade Secrets Protection Index Coverage,
Expanded Sample, 1985-2010
Trade Partner Economies (20)
OECD Countries (17)
Argentina
Brazil
Bulgaria
China
Colombia
Ghana
Hong Kong, China
India
Indonesia
Latvia
Lithuania
Malaysia
Peru
Philippines
Russia
Singapore
South Africa
Chinese Taipei
Thailand
Viet Nam
Australia
Canada
France
Germany
Ireland
Israel*
Italy
Japan
Korea
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Spain
Sweden
Turkey
United Kingdom
United States
Notes: The sample is an unbalanced panel. Not all countries are covered in every year.
* The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The use of such data by
the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the
terms of international law.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
189 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Chart 4.3.
Composition of the Patent Rights Index
1) Membership in International Treaties
Signatory
Not signatory
-- Paris Convention and Revisions
1/5
0
-- Patent Cooperation Treaty
1/5
0
-- Protection of New Varieties (UPOV78 or 91)
1/5
-- Budapest Treaty (Microorganism Deposits)
1/5
0
-- Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)
1/5
2) Coverage
Available
-- Patentability of pharmaceuticals
-- Patentability of chemicals
-- Patentability of food
-- Patentability of surgical products
-- Patentability of microorganisms
-- Patentability of utility models
-- Patentability of software
-- Patentability of plant & animal varieties
1/8
0
0
0
1/8
1/8
1/8
1/8
0
0
0
0
1/8
0
Does Not Exist
-- “Working” Requirements
-- Compulsory Licensing
-- Revocation of Patents
1/3
1/3
1/3
4) Enforcement
Not Available
1/3
1/3
1/3
5) Duration of Protection
Full
1
Exists
0
0
0
Available
-- Preliminary Injunctions
-- Contributory Infringement
-- Burden-of-Proof Reversal
0
Not Available
1/8
1/8
3) Restrictions on Patent Rights
0
0
0
0
Partial
0<f<1
-- where f is the duration
of protection as a fraction
of 20 years from the date
of application or 17 years
from the date of grant (for
grant-based
patent
systems).
Overall score for Patent Rights Index: sum of points under (1) – (5).
Note: The index was developed by Walter Park and colleagues at American University (Ginarte and Park, 1997;
Park, 2008).
Source: Park and Lippoldt (2008).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
190 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Chart 4.4.
Data Sources
1. OECD (2013 and 2014), OECD.Stat, (database); doi: 10.1787/data-00285-en.
•
GDP real in USD (2005) converted at purchasing power parity exchange rates
2. World Bank (2013 and 2014)
a. World Governance Indicators, on-line edition: http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home
•
Government effectiveness
b. World Development Indicators, on-line edition, http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-developmentindicators
•
•
•
•
•
•
GDP deflator (for use in calculations of constant value)
Population (for per capita calculations)
Researchers in R&D, per million people (NB: 1996 data assumed constant, used for 1995)
Resident and non-resident patent application data
R&D as a percent of GDP
Share of the labour force with tertiary education
3. Park (2008) and correspondence with the author, Walter Park, American University
•
Patent rights index
4.
UNCTAD
RF_ActivePath=P,5,27&sRF_Expanded=,P,5,27
•
http://unctadstat.unctad.org/ReportFolders/reportFolders.aspx?s
Foreign direct investment data
5.
International
Monetary
Fund,
Balance
http://elibrary-data.imf.org/finddatareports.aspx?d=33061&e=170784
•
of
Payments
Services imports, by sector
6. UN Comtrade Database http://comtrade.un.org/
•
Merchandise trade data
7. Fraser Institute, Economic Freedom of the World dataset, 2013, www.freetheworld.com/release.html
•
Chain-linked indices: Market regulation (area 5)
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
Statistics
191 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Table 4.1.
Trade Secret Protection Index: Statistics Scoring Using Alternative Weights, 2010
Total Scories, by Weighting Scheme
Equal weights:
20% for each
component
40% for
40% for Remedies
enforcement,
and restrictions on
investigation,
liability; 60%
discovery and data
divided equally
exclusivity; 60%
among the other
divided equally
components
amon the other
components
2.45
3.14
4.07
3.79
3.42
3.56
3.37
2.68
4.61
4.38
2.72
2.71
2.84
3.04
3.75
3.61
3.55
3.73
3.20
3.25
4.06
3.93
2.99
3.10
2.00
2.69
4.15
4.02
4.13
3.85
3.93
3.85
4.04
4.22
3.41
3.88
3.46
3.64
4.47
4.35
3.48
3.46
2.97
3.40
4.31
4.31
4.04
4.00
3.06
3.09
2.46
2.69
2.48
2.87
4.01
3.86
2.98
3.27
4.36
4.34
3.40
3.58
2.72
3.36
2.77
3.76
Argentina
Australia
Brazil
Bulgaria
Canada
China
Colombia
France
Germany
Ghana
Hong Kong, China
India
Indonesia
Ireland
Israel
Italy
Japan
Korea
Latvia
Lithuania
Malaysia
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Peru
Philippines
Russia
Singapore
South Africa
Spain
Sweden
Chinese Taipei
Thailand
3.12
3.99
3.31
2.96
4.48
2.71
3.15
3.76
3.76
3.43
4.03
2.92
2.52
4.15
4.08
3.85
4.27
3.81
3.64
4.44
3.48
3.32
4.22
4.04
3.06
2.45
2.47
4.00
3.14
4.42
3.56
3.12
3.42
Turkey
United Kingdom
United States
Viet Nam
3.41
3.97
4.49
3.01
2.83
4.12
4.55
3.16
3.47
3.71
4.62
3.17
Overall Average
Max
Median
Min
Standard Deviation
Coefficient of Variation
Correlation Coefficient (equal weight scores
versus alternate schemes)
Spearman Rank Correlation (equal weight
scores versus alternate schemes)
3.57
4.49
3.56
2.45
0.59
0.17
3.47
4.61
3.42
2.00
0.69
0.20
3.58
4.62
3.61
2.68
0.52
0.15
0.94
0.96
0.92
0.96
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
192 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Table 4.2.
Trade Secrets Protection Index, by economy and component, 2010
1. Definition and
coverage
2. Duties and
misappropriation
Normalised range
Argentina
Australia
Brazil
Bulgaria
Canada
China
Colombia
France
Germany
Ghana
Hong Kong, China
India
Indonesia
Ireland
Israel
Italy
Japan
Korea
Latvia
Lithuania
Malaysia
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Peru
Philippines
Russia
Singapore
South Africa
Spain
Sweden
Chinese Taipei
Thailand
Turkey
United Kingdom
United States
Vietnam
0-1
0.81
0.65
0.77
0.46
0.69
0.62
0.85
0.77
0.85
0.62
0.62
0.50
0.69
0.62
0.65
0.69
0.85
0.77
0.85
0.92
0.50
0.77
0.85
0.62
0.77
0.35
0.54
0.69
0.62
0.85
0.69
0.85
0.85
0.85
0.62
0.85
0.62
0-1
1.00
1.00
0.80
0.60
1.00
0.60
0.90
0.90
0.90
1.00
0.90
0.90
1.00
1.00
1.00
0.90
1.00
1.00
0.70
1.00
0.80
0.70
0.70
1.00
0.80
0.70
0.50
1.00
1.00
1.00
0.70
0.60
0.70
1.00
1.00
0.90
0.30
Overall Average
0.70
0.85
Components and scoring
4. Enforcement,
3. Remedies and
5. System
investigation and
restrictions on
functioning and
discovery; data
liability
related regulation
exclusivity
0-1
0-1
0-1
0.64
0.08
0.60
0.64
0.86
0.84
0.13
0.86
0.75
0.62
0.92
0.36
0.82
1.00
0.97
0.55
0.55
0.40
0.55
0.39
0.47
0.64
0.75
0.70
0.58
0.71
0.73
0.55
0.50
0.77
0.83
0.95
0.73
0.73
0.64
0.16
0.64
0.08
0.11
0.73
0.83
0.97
0.86
0.93
0.64
0.65
0.77
0.83
0.82
0.67
0.94
0.44
0.78
0.82
0.73
0.58
0.79
0.82
0.92
0.78
0.80
0.68
0.69
0.73
0.39
0.74
0.91
0.92
0.85
0.77
0.80
0.85
0.61
0.64
0.25
0.22
0.68
0.50
0.82
0.50
0.11
0.68
0.80
0.83
0.73
0.50
0.30
0.82
0.83
0.92
0.86
0.73
0.58
0.82
0.30
0.55
0.95
0.17
0.75
0.73
0.22
0.62
0.92
0.84
0.59
0.94
0.80
1.00
0.73
0.72
0.65
0.72
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
0.63
0.65
Totals
0-5
3.12
3.99
3.31
2.96
4.48
2.71
3.15
3.76
3.76
3.43
4.03
2.92
2.52
4.15
4.08
3.85
4.27
3.81
3.64
4.44
3.48
3.32
4.22
4.04
3.06
2.45
2.47
4.00
3.14
4.42
3.56
3.12
3.42
3.41
3.97
4.49
3.01
3.57
193 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Table 4.3.
Trade Secrets Protection Index, by economy and year, 1985-2010
Argentina
Australia
Brazil
Bulgaria
Canada
China
Colombia
France
Germany
Ghana
Hong Kong, China
India
Indonesia
Ireland
Israel
Italy
Japan
Korea
Latvia
Lithuania
Malaysia
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Peru
Philippines
Russia
Singapore
South Africa
Spain
Sweden
Chinese Taipei
Thailand
Turkey
United Kingdom
United States
Vietnam
Overall Average
3.76
3.04
2.85
3.54
2.10
2.29
3.19
3.83
4.11
1995
2.18
4.00
2.27
2.65
4.43
1.78
2.83
3.70
3.78
3.33
4.03
2.86
1.75
4.04
3.59
3.53
4.17
3.08
2.70
3.22
3.47
3.34
4.22
3.62
2.93
2.48
1.19
3.79
3.12
4.32
3.55
2.57
2.27
3.20
3.85
4.12
2000
3.16
4.01
3.15
2.64
4.44
2.22
2.92
3.72
3.78
3.29
4.01
2.86
2.50
4.04
3.82
3.56
4.17
3.69
3.32
4.11
3.44
3.32
4.24
3.62
2.98
2.47
1.63
3.79
3.13
4.32
3.55
2.88
2.28
3.21
3.98
4.54
2005
3.12
4.00
3.30
2.63
4.42
2.69
3.15
3.71
3.78
3.41
4.03
2.89
2.52
4.15
4.08
3.85
4.17
3.82
3.65
4.44
3.48
3.33
4.23
4.04
2.99
2.46
2.47
4.01
3.15
4.42
3.55
3.00
3.44
3.43
3.98
4.50
3.01
2010
3.12
3.99
3.31
2.96
4.48
2.71
3.15
3.76
3.76
3.43
4.03
2.92
2.52
4.15
4.08
3.85
4.27
3.81
3.64
4.44
3.48
3.32
4.22
4.04
3.06
2.45
2.47
4.00
3.14
4.42
3.56
3.12
3.42
3.41
3.97
4.49
3.01
3.12
3.22
3.41
3.55
3.57
1985
2.16
3.81
2.27
1990
2.19
3.81
2.28
4.12
2.84
3.40
3.26
3.24
3.87
2.83
1.77
3.76
3.59
3.54
4.06
2.16
4.14
0.90
2.84
3.71
3.77
3.32
3.86
2.82
1.78
4.01
3.53
3.56
4.07
2.19
3.46
1.67
3.87
3.59
2.64
2.75
3.46
1.95
4.21
3.60
2.66
2.41
3.76
3.08
2.61
2.28
2.10
2.28
3.22
3.47
4.11
3.08
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
Table 4.4.
194 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Illustrative Modelling of Relationship of TSPI to Selected Economic Performance Indicators (All variables entered as natural logarithms)
(1) Real R&D, per
capita (constant
USD, 2005)
(5) Change in real
foreign technological
services imports
(4) Change in real
(e.g., licencing &
services imports, per royalty payments for
capita (constant
intangibles), constant
(2) R&D personnel,
USD, 2005); all
USD (2005); all
as % of the labour (3) Real FDI inflows
variables entered
variables entered
(constant USD, 2005) as first differences as first differences
force
TSPI
TSPI lagged 1 period
1.494783 **
0.608775
0.583355 **
0.248242
0.782631 ***
0.293873
GDP per capita (real, USD 2005)
Market Regulation (Fraser Institute)
1.170749 ***
0.128488
-0.174773
0.304992
Share of labour force with tertiary education
Country Fixed Effects
Periods included
Years
Adjusted R2
Countries Covered (see note)
N
1.380278 **
0.568653
0.664822 **
0.258105
0.469547 **
0.195527
Interact (TSPI x Patent Rights Index)
GDP (real, USD 2005 ppp)
0.551834 **
0.228515
(6) Real
merchandise
imports (constant
USD, 2005)
Yes
Yes
4
1995-2010
0.987531
24
80
5
1990-2010
0.902006
20
82
2.047991 ***
0.313472
2.472000 ***
0.279946
1.412879 **
0.664468
0.778480 ***
0.219858
Yes
5
1990-2010
0.953125
23
64
1.231150 ***
0.097923
1.419025 **
0.697704
0.857275
0.682397
0.426688
0.285595
Yes
Yes
Yes
5
1990-2010
0.421721
23
109
5
1990-2010
0.407905
23
93
5
1990-2010
0.971826
24
110
Note: Statistical significance is shown as follows: * p< 0.05, ** p< 0.01, *** p< 0.01. Standard errors are shown in italics. For each regression run (1 to 6), the country coverage is: (1)
Australia, Canada, China, Colombia, France, Germany, India, Indonesia, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Russia, Singapore, South Africa,
Spain, Sweden, Turkey, United Kingdom, United States; (2) Australia, Canada, China, France, Germany, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand,
Russia, Singapore, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Turkey, United Kingdom; (3) Australia, Canada, China, Colombia, France, Germany, Indonesia, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea,
Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Russia, Singapore, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Turkey, United Kingdom and United States; (4) Same as (3) above; (5) Same as (3) above; (6)
Same as (1) above. The Patent Rights Index was only considered in the second regression run shown in the table, as part of the variable “Interact”.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
195 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Figure 4.1.
Trade Secrets Protection Index, By Economy and Component, 2010
1. Definition and coverage
2. Duties and misappropriation
3. Remedies and restrictions on liability
4. Enforcement, investigation and discovery; data exclusivity
5. System functioning and related regulation
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
196 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Figure 4.2.
Trade Secrets Protection Index, average score by country group and year
Trade Partner Countries (15)
OECD Economies (17)
4.50
4.00
3.50
3.00
2.50
2.00
1.50
1.00
0.50
0.00
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Note: This chart presents a balanced panel of economies in each group for which data were available in each of the years shown.
Inclusion in the OECD group is based on each country’s membership status as of 2010. Country coverage is as follows:
Trade partner economies: Argentina; Brazil; China; Colombia; Ghana; Hong Kong, China; India; Indonesia; Malaysia; Peru;
Philippines; Singapore; South Africa; Chinese Taipei; Thailand;
OECD countries: Australia; Canada; France; Germany; Ireland; Israel; Italy; Japan; Korea; Mexico; Netherlands; New Zealand; Spain;
Sweden; Turkey; United Kingdom; United States
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
197 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Figure 4.3.
Trade Secrets Protection Index, by country and year
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
198 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Figure 4.4.
Illustrative Scatter Plots
Panel A. R&D as % GDP (vertical axis) and Trade Secrets Protection Index (horizontal axis)
Panel B. Real Foreign Technological Services Imports (log, vertical axis) and
Trade Secrets Protection Index (horizontal axis)
5
y = 4.0921x + 0.6792
R² = 0.1909
4
3
2
1
0
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
-1
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
0.5
0.6
0.7
199 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Figure 4.5.
TSPI & Econ Performance, 1990 – 2010
(1% change in TSPI = x % change in…)
1.60
1.40
1.20
1.00
0.80
0.60
0.40
0.20
0.00
Real R&D
expenditures,
per capita
Real FDI inflows Change in real Change in real Change in real
services imports,
foreign
merchandise
per capita (1st technological
imports
differences) services imports
(1st differences)
Note: The bars represent the coefficients from regression of various indicators of economic performance on the TSPI controlling for
other factors. All variables entered as natural logarithms. For the iteration with real R&D expenditures per capita the TSPI was lagged
one period. For the services runs the regression was calculated using first differences.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
200 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
ANNEX
Due to the annex’s length, interested readers are referred to the original version of this chapter, which
is an OECD Trade Policy Working Paper, available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jxzl5w3j3s6-en (Lippoldt
& Schultz, 2014).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
201 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
NOTES
116
For descriptive convenience this chapter will employ the term “trade secrets” as encompassing
“undisclosed information.”
117
See Chapter 3, section 2 for further details on the international framework for the protection of trade
secrets.
118
Moreover, as Pooley (1997) notes, the idea need not be unique to its owner. Several competitors could
have developed the same idea via independent innovation and sought to protect it as a trade secret. This
possibility is one factor differentiating trade secrets from patents.
119
However, some countries impose more specific, additional obligations, which might be characterized as a
particular implementation of the broad reasonableness requirement. For example, some common law
countries require that the defendant have a contractual or implied obligation to keep the information
secret. Other countries require written agreements with recipients and confidentiality notices.
120
This example highlights the importance of empirical research in considering the relationship of trade
secrets protection to economic performance. For example, such competition could possibly lead to
disincentives to invest, to inefficiencies (e.g. due to overlapping research) or to increased innovation
building on knowledge spillovers, among other possibilities. The net effects can be difficult to determine
in advance and it is necessary to examine the experience in practice.
121
Further discussion of non-compete provisions can be found in Chapter 3.
122
One important issue for mobility concerns investment by firms in training of employees. Firms cannot
generally restrain employee use of general skills and knowledge (e.g. from training that is widely
available). However, when a firm invests substantial time and resources in training an employee in its
own technical products, courts in some jurisdictions may find that the firm has a legitimate business
interest that may appropriately be protected via a limited non-compete clause in a labour contract (e.g.
Swift, 2007). Where firms face high employee mobility, their incentive to invest in such training in
principle could be supported by availability of this protection. Yet, validity of any claims may be difficult
for an employer to demonstrate (e.g. Lester, 2001). Thus, some firms may utilise alternative approaches
such as contractual requirements for employees to reimburse training costs under certain conditions
(Lester, 2001) or payment of wage premia to discourage employee separations (Fosfuri et al., 2001),
among other options.
123
Depending on the circumstances, this might be accomplished for example via such means as nondisclosure agreements with employees and commercial partners or basic digital or physical security
measures.
124
Certainly, patents can play other important roles for some SMEs, such as cultivation of public recognition
of a firm’s innovative capacity or mobilisation of new investor capital, among other possibilities.
125
With small patent portfolios, some SMEs may have limited bargaining power to settle with bigger players
who confront them. Also, SMEs may tend to be less financially able to withstand an expensive legal
challenge to a patent (e.g. from a non-practicing entity).
126
This is part of a larger discussion in the literature concerning approaches used by firms and others to
appropriate returns on their investments and innovations. For example, see: Denicoló and Franzoni (2004)
and Anton and Yao (2004), among others.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
202 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
127
For example, some observers have expressed concerns on behalf of SMEs. These firms are known as
being particularly reliant on trade secrets protection and may find increased opportunities for international
expansion under improved conditions of protection for trade secrets.
128
The draft directive and related materials are available on line, here (as of 23 May 2014):
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/iprenforcement/trade_secrets/index_en.htm#maincontentSec1 .
129
This strategy is available on-line at the following location (as of 3 April 2013):
www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/IPEC/admin_strategy_on_mitigating_the_theft_of_u.s._trad
e_secrets.pdf.
130
A recent example of response to espionage and abuse of trade secrets can be found in a US Federal
Government court case launched against five Chinese military officials for allegedly hacking into
computers at five US companies. US officials are considering the possibility of reinforcing their response
in light of such espionage, including potentially freezing assets or using individual sanctions such as visa
restrictions, or possibly national-level action at the World Trade Organisation. Source: Wall Street
Journal, 2014, “US to Rev Up Hacking Fight”, 23 May.
131
For example, component 4 Enforcement, investigation and discovery; data exclusivity is comprised of six
elements. The value for the Component 4 score can range from 0 to one. In the final calculation of the
score for the overall component, the scores for any given element would be no more than 1/6 of one point.
This would be the case, for example, for data exclusivity for drugs or data exclusivity for agricultural
chemicals (each would contribute no more than 1/6 of one point to the component score).
132
The development of this index is a pioneering effort in the analysis of protection of trade secrets.
However, it should be noted that a variety of similar indices exist in the literature covering various types
of intellectual property. For example, Ginarte and Park (1997) and Park (2008) employed laws-on-thebooks approaches to examine protection of patents, trademarks and copyright. Pugatch et al. (2014)
developed an empirically based index of the strength of IPR protection, which also incorporated industry
perspectives. Png (2012a and b) developed an indicator for use in his analytical work on trade secrets
protection. Also, the Fraser Institute (2013) and World Economic Forum, among others, have developed
substantial sets of relevant systemic indicators for use in economic analyses. Such indicators have been
utilised in a number of studies conducted by the Working Party of the Trade Committee and other parts of
OECD. Several Trade Committee studies considered policies for protection of intellectual property rights
in relation to relevant economic performance indicators. OLIS references include:
TD/TC/WP(2002)42/FINAL,
TD/TC/WP(2004)31/FINAL,
TAD/TC/WP(2007)19/FINAL
and
TAD/TC/WP(2010)12/FINAL. Subsequent OECD Trade Policy Working Papers were published as: Park
and Lippoldt (2003); Park and Lippoldt (2005); Park and Lippoldt (2008); and Cavazos, Lippoldt and
Senft (2010). More information on the construction of composite indicators can be found in OECD-EU
(2008).
133
Note that alternative indicators of trade secrets protection could be developed for more specific, targeted
policy development purposes; for example, one could focus exclusively on civil law in a future
assessment. For readers interested in such exploration, the Annex table has the detailed country scoring
information; readers can thus mix, match and recombine the numbers as they see fit. Moreover, additional
aspects might be taken into account. For example, the transparency benefits from having a specific trade
secrets statute might be noted or, for those not from a common law background, the challenge of
understanding the protection afforded based on court precedent. Also, in the next stage of this line of
research, a useful check on the construction of the TSPI would be to confirm the results using a principle
components assessment.
134
The additional economies covered by this iteration of the TSPI include: Argentina; Canada; Ghana; Hong
Kong, China; Indonesia; Ireland; Latvia; Lithuania; Mexico; Netherlands; Philippines; Spain; Chinese
Taipei; Thailand; Turkey; and Viet Nam. Also, the scoring for certain of the countries originally covered
in Chapter 3 has been updated throughout in light of newly available information and improved precision
in the weighting.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
203 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
135
Annex Table 1 provides the detailed scoring for each element and component of the index for each
country. In the event a user would like to consider alternative approaches to constructing indicators, these
data will provide the essential building blocks (e.g., for recombining various elements or reweighting the
components).
136
For some transition countries, the observations start in 1990 (China) or 1995 (Bulgaria, Latvia, Lithuania
and Russia).
137
The sample ranges are broader for earlier years, as can be seen below in Table 3.
138
See endnote 17.
139
With respect to endogeneity, there are a few technical options available to address these issues, if
necessary. One option (used below in one model specification) is to lag time series by one or more
periods.
140
In part, the choice of correction approach was made taking into account the sample sizes (e.g. see Clark
and Linzer, 2012) and Hausman test results.
141
The regression analyses were run using Eviews software and a least squares method.
142
The Patent Rights Index is comprised of five components including: membership in international treaties,
coverage by subject matter, restrictions on patent rights, enforcement provisions, and duration of
protection. Scores for each component range from zero to one and the index total is calculated as the sum
of the scores for the five components, which are equally weighted.
143
Ideally, the regression specified in part (1) would be run separately to consider Business Expenditure on
R&D (BERD) instead of economy-wide R&D. However, this could not be done here due to lack of data
(only 24 observations were available for the countries and time period covered here). The use of
economy-wide R&D could lead to lower statistical significance or introduce a downward bias in the TSPI
coefficient in comparison to use of BERD. This is because economy-wide R&D may include public
sector and academic institutions where trade secrets might be expected to play less of a role as compared
to businesses.
144
In this specification, the association between the TSPI and R&D expenditure appears robust to the
lagging of the TSPI variable by one period. Further research could consider additional aspects of potential
endogeneity. For example, it may be that accumulation of intellectual assets could fuel demand for further
protection of intellectual property (here, taken as including trade secrets) such that there is a feedback
effect (e.g. Lippoldt, 2011, p 188). Moreover, the relationships between the variables as dependent or
independent (falling on the left or right hand of the models, as specified) could be explored, along with
implications for policy formation.
145
In a future analysis, it could be useful to consider developments from an evolutionary perspective to
determine whether the relationship of changes in stringency to economic indicators may be nonmonotonic for different degrees of stringency.
146
For example, in relation to the stringency of trade secret protection, it could be useful to consider
inter-industry variation in strategies for appropriating benefits from innovation and investment.
147
E.g. the duty of confidentiality might be imposed on employees, fiduciaries and third parties with access
to information. Partial coverage might arise if under a country’s legal regime licensees cannot be
covered.
148
The treatment of duties is split within this framework. General coverage of duties is scored under index
component 1 (Definitions & Coverage). Component 2 responds to the availability of recourse for specific
duties. This permits a detailed assessment, ensuring the indicator responds to variation in key elements.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
204 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
149
The Fraser Institute (2012, pp. 3 and 273-5) score for Legal System and Security of Property Rights is a
composite indicator produced annually. Scores can range from 0 to 10. Based on objective indicators and
expert assessments, it takes into account judicial independence, impartiality of courts, protection of
property rights, military interference in the rule of law and politics, integrity of the legal system, legal
enforcement of contracts, regulatory restrictions on the sale of real property, reliability of the police and
business costs of crime. For details see Annex 1 of the present report and
www.freetheworld.com/reports.html.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
205 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
REFERENCES
Anton, J. J. & D.A. Yao (2004), “Little patents and big secrets: managing intellectual property,”
RAND Journal of Economics, 1-22,
www.jstor.org/stable/1593727?__redirected.
Arundel, A. (2001), “The Relative Effectiveness of Patents and Secrecy for Appropriation”,
30 Research Policy, 611–624.
Audretsch, D.B., A.J. Menkveld & A.R. Thurik (1996), “The Decision Between Internal and
External R&D”, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE) / Zeitschrift für die
gesamte Staatswissenschaft, Vol. 152, No. 3 519-530.
Baker & McKenzie (2013), Study on Trade Secrets and Confidential Business Information in the
Internal Market, prepared for the European Commission (EC).
Barbieri, S.F. et al. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law,
International Association for the Protection of Intellectual Property (AIPPI) Report Q215,
Canada”.
Brant, J. & S. Lohse (2013), Enhancing IP Management and Appropriation by Innovative SMEs,
International Chamber of Commerce, available at (as of 23 February 2014): www.iccdeutschland.de/fileadmin/ICC_Dokumente/Dokumente/PIA_SME_ENG_email_1_.pdf.
Cavazos Cepeda, R., D. Lippoldt and J. Senft (2010), “Policy Complements to the Strengthening of
IPRS in Developing Countries”, OECD Trade Policy Papers, No. 104, OECD Publishing,
[TAD/TC/WP(2010)12/FINAL].
Cohen, W., R. Nelson & J. Walsh (2000), “Protecting their Intellectual Assets: Appropriability
Conditions and Why U.S. Manufacturing Firms Patent (Or Not)”, NBER Working Paper,
W7552, www.nber.org/papers/w7552.pdf.
Clark, T.S. & D.A. Linzer (2012), “Should I Use Fixed or Random Effects”, mimeo, Emory
University.
CREATe (2014), Economic Impact of Trade Secret Theft: A Framework for Companies to
Safeguard Trade Secrets and Mitigate Potential Threats, Centre for Responsible Enterprise and
Trade and PWC, February.
CREATe (2012), Trade Secret Theft: Managing the Growing Threat in Supply Chains, Center for
Responsible Enterprise and Trade (CREATe), available here (as of 23 February 2014):
www.create.org/news-resources/resources/trade-secret-theft-supply-chains.
Denicolo, V., & A. L. Franzoni (2004), “Patents, Secrets, and the First‐Inventor Defense,” Journal
of Economics & Management Strategy, 13(3), 517-538,
http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1430-9134.2004.00021.x/full.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
206 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Felix, N.S. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215, Argentina.
Fosfuri, A., M. Motta & T. Rønde (2001), “Foreign direct investment and spillovers through
workers’ mobility,” Journal of International Economics, vol. 53(1), pp 205-22.
Fraser Institute (2013), Economic Freedom of the World 2013 Annual Report, J. Gwartney,
R. Lawson and J. Hall, available as of 15 February 2014 at:
www.freetheworld.com/reports.html.
Friedman, D.D., W.M. Landes & R.A. Posner (1991), “Some Economics of Trade Secret Law”,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5 (Winter), pp. 61-72.
Ginarte, J.C. & W.G. Park (1997), “Determinants of Patent Rights: A Cross-National Study”,
Research Policy, Vol. 26, 283-301.
Gomes-Casseres, B. (1997), “Alliance Strategies of Small Firms”, Small Business Economics,
Vol. 9, Issue 1, pp. 33-44, available at (as of 20 February 2014):
http://link.springer.com/article/10.1023/A:1007947629435#.
Hogan Lovells (2012), Study on Trade Secrets and Parasitic Copying (Look-alikes),
MARKT/2010/20/D, prepared for the European Commission (EC) by Hogan Lovells
International LLP.
Işık, S. et al. (2011), Protection of Trade Secrets Under Turkish Law, Mehmet Gun & Partners
Website.
Kamphausen, R. (2014), New Collaborative Approaches to IP Protection, Working Paper, The
National Bureau of Asian Research (NBR), May.
Kitch, E.W. (1980), “The Law and Economics of Rights in Valuable Information”, 9 Journal of
Legal Studies, 683.
Krodere-Imsa, I. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law,
AIPPI Report Q215, Latvia.
Lanjouw, J.O. & M. Schankerman (2004), “Protecting Intellectual Property Rights: Are Small Firms
Handicapped?”, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 47, No. 1, pp. 45-74, April.
Lemley, M.A. (2011), “The Surprising Virtues of Treating Trade Secrets as IP rights”, in R.C.
Dreyfuss and K.J. Strandburg (eds.), The Law and Theory of Trade Secrecy: A Handbook of
Contemporary Research, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.
Lester, G. (2001), “Restrictive Covenants, Employee Training, and the Limits of Transaction-Cost
Analysis,” Indiana Law Journal, vol. 76, issue 1, article 4.
Lippoldt, D.C. (2011), Patent Rights, Developing Countries and the Economic Influence of the
Multilateral Trading System, SciencesPo, Paris, available at:
http://spire.sciences-po.fr/hdl:/2441/f4rshpf3v1umfa09lass9h1s2 (as of 19 February 2014).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
207 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
Lippoldt, D.C. & M.F. Schultz (2014), “Uncovering Trade Secrets – An Empirical Assessment of
Economic Implications of Protection for Undisclosed Information”, OECD Trade Policy
Papers, No. 167, OECD Publishing, www.oecd.org/trade.
Llevet, J. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215, Spain.
Lokshin, Boris et al. (2006), “Internal and External R&D: Complements or Substitutes? Evidence
from a Dynamic Panel Data Model”, Working Paper, available as of 11 February 2014 at:
www.econ.kuleuven.be/fetew/pdf_publicaties/MSI_0604.pdf.
MacLaren, T. (2012), Trade Secrets Throughout the World, database update, Thomson/West,
Eagan, MN, USA.
Margaín, M. et al. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law,
AIPPI Report Q215, Mexico.
Maskus, K.E. (2000), Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Economy, Institute for International
Economics.
Noerhadi, C.C. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215, Indonesia.
OECD-EU (2008), Handbook on Constructing Composite Indicators: Methodology and User
Guide, OECD and European Union, Joint Research Centre-European Commission, OECD
Publishing, Paris, DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264043466-en.
Oztek, S. et al. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215, Turkey.
Park, W.G. (2008), “International Patent Protection: 1960-2005”, Research Policy, No. 37, 761-766.
Park, W.G. & D. Lippoldt (2008), “Technology Transfer and the Economic Implications of the
Strengthening of Intellectual Property Rights in Developing Countries”, Trade Policy Working
Paper, No. 62, OECD, Paris, available here (as of 23 February 2014):
www.sourceoecd.org/10.1787/244764462745.
Park, W. & D. Lippoldt (2005), “International Licensing and The Strengthening of Intellectual
Property Rights in Developing Countries During The 1990s”, OECD Economic Studies, Vol.
40, Paris.
Park, W. & D. Lippoldt (2003), “The Impact of Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights on Trade
and Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries”, OECD Papers, Vol. 3, No. 11, paper
294.
Png, I. (2012a), Law and Innovation: Evidence from State Trade Secrets Laws, mimeo, National
University of Singapore, SSRN.
Png, I. (2012b), “Trade Secrets, Non-Competes, and Mobility of Engineers and Scientists:
Empirical Evidence”, mimeo, National University of Singapore, SSRN.
Pooley, J. (1997), Trade Secrets, Law Journal Seminars-Press, New York, NY, (This is a
comprehensive legal treatise, with annual supplements. At the time of the present research, the
current edition is Release 31, 2013).
Primo Braga, C. (1990), “Guidance from Economic Theory”, in Strengthening Protection of
Intellectual Property in Developing Countries: A Survey of the Literature, Wolfgang Siebeck,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
208 | AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF PROTECTION FOR TRADE SECRETS
editor, with R.E. Evenson, W. Lesser and C.A. Primo Braga, World Bank Discussion Paper
No. 112, pp. 17-32.
Pugatch, M., R. Chu and D. Torstensson (2014), Charting the Course, Second Edition, The Global
Intellectual Property Center, US Chamber of Commerce, available here (as of 25 February
2014):
www.theglobalipcenter.com/wp-content/themes/gipc/mapindex/assets/pdf/Index_Map_Index_2ndEdition.pdf.
Schultz, M.F. & D.C. Lippoldt (2014), “Approaches to Protection of Undisclosed Information
(Trade Secrets): Background Paper”, OECD Trade Policy Papers, No. 162, OECD Publishing.
doi: 10.1787/5jz9z43w0jnw-en.
Sherwood, R.M. (1990), Intellectual Property and Economic Development, Westview Special
Studies in Science, Technology, and Public Policy.
Sujintaya, S. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law, AIPPI
Report Q215, Thailand.
Swift, K.R. (2007), “Void Agreements, Knocked-Out Terms, and Blue Pencils: Judicial and
Legislative Handling of Unreasonable Terms in Noncompete Agreements”, Hofstra Labor and
Employment Law Journal, vol. 24, pp. 233-4.
van Dijk, J.W. et al. (2010), Protection of Trade Secrets Through IP and Unfair Competition Law,
AIPPI Report Q215, Netherlands.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
209 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
CHAPTER 5. COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
This chapter illustrates how copyright-intensive industries are performing and evolving in light of the
changes brought about by the growth of the Internet, digitisation, and an increasingly globalised market
for digital content. The salient economic properties of digital content are explained and the main
copyright-intensive industries are identified. A set of country studies then presents objective
information on the economic significance of copyright in a sample of 12 economies over time 150. In
addition to characterising how copyright-intensive industries have fared, the country studies summarise
the principal characteristics of each economy’s copyright laws, as well as how and why they have
evolved (if at all) in recent years. Finally, the country studies provide a summary of the mainstream
policy dialogues currently taking place in each economy.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities or third
party. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and
Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
It should be noted that statistical data on Israeli patents and trademarks are supplied by the patent and trademark
offices of the relevant countries.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
210 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
The technological revolution and the economic performance of copyright-intensive industries
The Internet and its ecosystem form an ever-evolving landscape, in which content producers and
content users constantly face dynamic technological innovation and rapid commercial development. Longpredicted trends such as the convergence of previously distinct communication services are now occurring
at a fast pace across all sectors of industry and having profound and widespread impacts on economies and
societies.
The Internet is still growing strongly, particularly in the mobile segment. The average subscription
rate of mobile broadband Internet access in OECD countries as a whole rose to 72% in December 2013, up
from just 32% in December 2009 (Figure 5.1). In the fixed broadband category, growth of the Internet is
slower, as might be expected given the widespread adoption of this technology. At the end of 2013, the
average penetration rate of fixed broadband access in OECD countries was 27 per 100 inhabitants, versus
23 at the end of 2009, and versus 4.8 in 2002 (Figure 5.1.).
Figure 5.1.
The recent development of broadband Internet
(OECD average, per 100 inhabitants)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
The observed trends in the broadband penetration rates, especially fixed broadband, are a strong
indication of the Internet’s maturity in the OECD countries. Consequently, this general-purpose technology
has impacted many industries, including the copyright-intensive ones.
It should be kept in mind that due to different statistical taxonomies from one country to the next, no
macroeconomic picture of the copyright-intensive sector can be drawn that is strictly comparable across
economies. Even though some correspondence tables can be found for the different taxonomies used in the
economies analysed in this chapter, in many instances there are no straightforward equivalences between
various industry classifications systems.
Nevertheless, some general indications can be presented based on the observed signals. These are i)
the value added generated by the copyright-intensive industries and ii) the number of people they employ.
However, caution should be used when comparing these results across economies, since they cannot be
perceived as direct equivalents.
Concerning value added, over the past ten years the copyright-intensive industries have demonstrated
overall good performance. In most of the analysed economies these industries reported positive growth of
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
211 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
their value added. At the same time, due to higher growth in other sectors, the share of the copyright-based
industries in total GDP remained rather stable ranging from a 1.5 percentage point (pp) decline to a 0.9 pp
increase.
In most of the analysed countries, copyright intensive industries accounted for up to 5% of GDP at the
end of the analysed period. (See Table 5.1.)
Table 5.1.
Economy
Analysed
period
Value added generated by copyright-intensive industries.
Development in
absolute terms
Development in
relative terms
(change in value added)
(change in GDP share)
Share in GDP
(at the end of the
analysed period)
Australia
2002-2012
9% growth
(CAGR 0.8%)
1.5 percentage point (pp)
reduction
5%
Canada
2003-2012
16.4% growth
(CAGR 1.7%)
Remained stable
3.18%
Chile*
2009
n.a.
n.a.
1.58 %
Egypt*
2000
n.a.
n.a.
up to 0.5%
European Union
2010
n.a.
n.a.
4,2%
Italy
2008-2011
Growth
Remained stable
3,65%
Japan
1998, 2007
57% growth
0.9 pp increase
3,4%
Korea
2009-2011
36 % growth
0.8 pp increase
4,37%
Poland
2008-2011
Growth
Remained stable
4,17%
Switzerland*
1997-2011
Small growth
(CAGR 0.3%)
Small reduction
0,3%
United Kingdom
2008-2012
15.6% growth
Increase
5,2%
United States**
2000 - 2012
70% (80%) growth
(CAGR 4.52% (5%))
0.6 pp (0.4 pp) increase
4,7%
*) For Chile, Egypt and Switzerland: The available data are not compatible with WIPO (2003)
**) For the United States: Two alternative methodologies are applied to determine the copyright-intensive industries: ESA-USPTO
(2010) and Siwek and IIPA (2004) (the figure representing the share in the economy using the latter methodology is in parentheses).
The available data on people employed by the copyright-intensive industries also point at their
relative stability. In the most recent year for which data are available (depending on the economy), this
sector accounted for 2.3% to 5.6% of total employment in the analysed economies. This share has been
remained mostly stable through the analysed periods (Table 5.2.).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
212 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Table 5.2.
Employment in copyright-intensive industries
Economy
Analysed
period
Development in
absolute terms
(change in number of
employees)
Development in relative
terms
(change in share of total
employment)
Share in total
employment
(at the end of the
analysed period)
Australia
2002-2012
Slight growth by 1.6%
Slight reduction by
1 percentage point (pp)
5.5% (2011)
Canada
2003-2012
11.3% growth
(CAGR 1.3%)
Remained constant
2.9% (2012)
Chile*
2009
n.a.
n.a.
2.3 %
Egypt*
2000
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
European Union
2010
n.a.
n.a.
3.2%
Italy
2008-2011
Slight reduction
Relatively stable
2.3%
Japan
1998, 2007
8.8% growth
0.4 pp increase
3%
Korea
2009-2011
13% growth
0.3 pp increase
3.1%
Poland
2008-2011
Slight reduction
Remained stable
2.3%
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
United Kingdom
2011-2012
Growth
0.5 pp increase
5,6%
United States**
2000 - 2011
Relatively stable
Relatively stable
3,0% (3.2%)
Switzerland*
*) For Chile, Egypt and Switzerland: The available data are not compatible with WIPO (2003)
**) For the United States: Two alternative methodologies are applied to determine the copyright-intensive industries:
ESA-USPTO (2010) and Siwek and IIPA (2004) (the figure representing the share in the economy using the latter methodology is in
parentheses).
The generally non-negative performance of copyright-intensive industries suggests that this sector
has, overall, managed to adapt to the continuous developments in technological infrastructure. In fact as
technology continues to evolve, improve and expand, a growing number of services within the copyrightintensive sector rely on new, innovative business models that i) use the Internet as a new way to deliver
content ii) take advantage of improved portability of content or iii) introduce other new ways of generating
revenue.
Most new business models in that sector rely on the Internet as a new way of content delivery. The
most well-known example is iTunes, the global digital media store operated by Apple that fully relies on
the Internet to deliver content. Other examples of such business models (presented in greater detail in the
main body of the paper) include Quickflix is Australia (subscriptions to streamed television shows),
Stingray Digital Group in Canada (interactive online music broadcasting and distribution), Italian Chili-TV
(Internet platform for movie streaming and downloads), NCSOFT Corporation in Korea (publisher of
massively multiplayer online games) and Muzo.pl and muzodajnia.pl in Poland (on-line music retailer).
In addition, some new business models take advantage of improved portability of content thanks to
growing penetration of mobile devices such as smartphones or tablets. This includes such firms like Kobo,
a Canadian producer of e-book readers, and some Japanese companies that take advantage of the high
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
213 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
penetration of mobile internet access in that country, such as Namco Bandai Games, which develops video
games for mobile phones.
Moreover, some business models rely on new ways of generating revenue such as ad-based models
and subscription-based models. These include successful subscription-based services such as Netflix and
Japanese cell-phone novel providers. Another example is Canada’s Têtes à Claques, a French-language
comedy website that generates a large share of their revenues through ad campaigns, licensing the
characters for labels of commercial products, etc.
To re-iterate, it seems that the copyright-intensive industries in the analysed countries are, have made
efforts to adapt to the new challenges and opportunities introduced by the Internet, and that in many cases
these efforts turned out to be successful. That is not to say that all individual sectors have fully adjusted,
nor is it to say that piracy is not a significant problem, but the copyright-intensive industries as a group
appear to be achieving stable results in terms of value added and employment, even though in some cases
they grow at smaller rates than the overall economy. It is likely that negative effects on value added and
employment from technological advances are being at least partially offset by newer, innovative business
models that take advantage of the business opportunities offered by the Internet.
Evolving legal frameworks and the surrounding debates
In each analysed economy policy makers recognize the importance of copyright-related legislation
as a tool to maximise innovation and creativity. These legal copyright frameworks were established well
before the Internet revolution. Today each analysed economy has amended, currently amends or is going to
amend its copyright legislative frameworks in order to bring these frameworks up to date with
contemporary uses of technology. One of the first amendments was the Digital Millennium Copyright Act
(DMCA) in the United States, enacted in 1998. In 2001 the European Union adopted the so-called
Copyright Directive 151. In Canada, the Copyright Modernization Act was passed in 2012. Numerous
European countries have recently called for views for the debate, and several EU member states are
conducting debates on that topic.
The most common areas of amendments and current debates that were identified in the analysed
country studies are:
•
scope of copyrights
•
orphan works
•
copyright limitations and exceptions
•
copyright registration
•
enforcement
It should be highlighted that there is a diverse set of views regarding optimal solutions in these areas,
and at this stage it is virtually impossible to assess which solutions were optimal and which were not. In
addition, this list of issues is not exhaustive, and in some economies there are several other copyrightrelated legal issues that were debated or are being currently debated in the context of the Internet
revolution.
In the context of technological progress it is important to notice the issues related to the scope of
copyright, particularly with respect to coverage of data and datasets. Indeed, rapid technological progress
is likely to permit economic use (and hence monetisation) of data, just as creative content can be monetised
today. Whereas all legal systems protect creative databases that constitute a creative compilation under
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
214 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
copyright law, some analysed economies (the European Union, and consequently The United Kingdom,
Italy and Poland) have also introduced additional legislation to cover non-creative databases that is
intended to strengthen the rights of database creators.
The phenomenon of orphan works 152 is also debated in almost all the analysed economies. Although
the issue of orphan works is not new, the emergence of the Internet and the resulting drastic reduction of
cost of transforming creative content have made this problem particularly striking. There are several ways
to address the legal treatment of orphan works. One existing solution is a kind of public license that can be
granted by public authorities (e.g. copyright office) after a party demonstrates that it made considerable
efforts to identify the rights owner. Such solutions were adopted in Canada, Japan and Korea. The EU
countries currently adopt the EU Directive on orphan works that sets rules on certain permitted uses of
such works, whereas Switzerland allows the use of such works contained in phonograms or audiovisual
fixations with a prior notification of collective societies.
Several countries do not have an explicit policy on orphan works. These countries either: are
discussing potential policies in this area (the United States), include orphan works in the public domain
(Chile), or advise some pre-cautionary steps to mitigate the risk, such as checking the publication date and
the date of author's death (Australia).
Concerning copyright limitations and exceptions, digital technology greatly reduces the cost of
copying, distributing and transforming content, which has led to the availability of more copyrighted
content and much wider usage of it than ever before and the corollary availability of pirated content. Policy
makers have taken the view that consumers should have the flexibility to make reasonable uses of
legitimately acquired copyrighted content in the digital age. All analysed economies have copyright
limitations and exceptions frameworks to allow certain unlicensed uses of copyrighted materials, e.g. for
personal use, review, criticism, parody, educational purposes, etc. To ensure that the legitimate interests of
rights holders are respected, laws typically include limitations restricting such content from being used for
commercial purposes or from interfering in markets for the original work. (Specific cases when copyright
exemptions apply are discussed in greater detail in the main body of the paper.)
Two things should be kept in mind in the context of copyright limitations and exceptions. First, in all
analysed economies the limitations and exceptions do not waive the author’s moral rights (such as the right
of authorship, the right of integrity of work and the right of divulgation). Second, continuous technological
progress keeps creating new possibilities for uses of copyrighted material, which in turn trigger discussions
about new potential copyright limitations and exceptions.
Coming back to the issue of orphan works, some researchers point at copyright registration as a
potential (partial) solution to this problem. Indeed, several analysed countries have introduced the option of
copyright registration as a voluntary mechanism that will benefit the rights holder in case of potential
disputes (Canada, Chile, Egypt, Italy, Japan, Korea, United States). Clearly, the orphan works regime is not
tied to copyright registration in any of the analysed countries. However, it is noteworthy that most analysed
countries decided to regulate at least one of these two areas: orphan works and copyright registration,
which suggests there might be some interactions (for example complementarities) between these two areas
(See Figure 5.2.).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
215 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.2.
Policies on orphan works and copyright registration*
Copyright registration
Possible
Not possible
Explicit policy on orphan works
Yes (debated)
No
Canada
Italy
Japan
Korea
Chile
Egypt
United States
Poland
Switzerland
United Kingdom
Australia
* The orphan works regime is not tied to copyright registration in any of the analysed countries.
The advent of the Internet has resulted in growing access to information worldwide. However this
also means that more and more consumers have access to pirated creative content. The legal and regulatory
frameworks aimed at preventing digital piracy are key jurisdictional factors, as they affect the behaviour of
the main market actors, but only to the extent that laws are enforced in practice. If the resources devoted to
enforcement are inadequate or intellectual property rights are not otherwise enforced by public authorities,
then the value of the laws and regulations to the rights holders is low (OECD, 2009b).
In the analysed economies, copyright infringement is generally pursued by the copyright owner.
However, in some cases (e.g. commercial scale piracy) the infringement may also be subject to ex officio
criminal proceedings. To address this issue, some countries have devoted special police units to counter
online IP crime (United Kingdom, Korea). In addition, some countries have considered new legislation to
block websites that host copyright-infringing materials (for example Italy and the United States).
Furthermore, many countries have been introducing liability for circumventing, and facilitating the
circumvention of, technological protection measures that restrict access to copyrighted works and/or seek
to preclude the infringement of digital copyrighted material (e.g. Canada, the EU, United States). These
measures, required by some WIPO treaties 153, are broad in scope, and preclude ‘descrambling’, decrypting
or acts that otherwise avoid, bypass, remove, deactivate or impair a technological measure.
In almost all the analysed economies there have been robust discussions of a broad range of issues
related to “copyright in the age of the Internet”. These discussions have involved the government, industry,
academia, and civil society, and preceded amendments of copyright legislation in many areas, some of
which are summarised above.
The copyright-intensive industries are an important participant in these debates. In all the analysed
economies, these industries are also represented or complemented by a number of usually sector-specific
associations (music, film and television, books and periodicals, software, visual arts, etc.). Apart from
participation in the debate, these associations carry out several activities, including: i) collective rights
management, ii) awareness raising campaigns in the area of copyright, concerning, e.g. security awareness
and attitudes towards digital piracy, iii) data collection, and iv) promoting best practices.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
216 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Likely due to the ever-increasing rise and effect of piracy in the digital age 154, much of the copyrightintensive industries’ effort seems to concentrate in the area of online copyright enforcement. In most cases
it includes industry best practices to counter digital piracy (e.g. Korea, United Kingdom, United States).
Lastly, the industry is also an important source of information on data, including statistical data and
research as well as qualitative information. Data and economic analyses provided by the industry are
essential to understand the way the industry operates and to predict its future development.
Introduction and Background
The Internet has become a vital platform for delivering digital content such as movies, music, books,
news, and software. Most importantly, the global reach of the Internet enables digital content to be nearly
instantaneously delivered to any part of the world. This means that many of the barriers that constrain the
exchange of physical content products (e.g. costly transportation, import tariffs) are significantly reduced
or eliminated in the case of digital content. It also underscores the importance of copyright as an incentive
mechanism for the creation and dissemination of digital content.
Digital content is flourishing on the Internet according to a range of indicators. Data also indicate that
a significant portion of traffic is infringing, notwithstanding the fact that the vast majority of the most
popular works are available legitimately online 155. While official estimates are not available, Cisco has
estimated that all forms of video (i.e. TV, video on demand, Internet, and P2P) will account for
approximately 90 percent of total consumer Internet traffic by 2015 (Cisco, 2013). Another example is the
recent rapid growth of sites that allow users to upload and share content on the Internet. It is estimated that
the photo sharing site Flickr alone reached 1.6 million photos uploaded daily on average on its platform in
2013 156.
Policy makers continue to promote the creation and dissemination of digital content, and effective
copyright policy (including its enforcement) is central to their success. The 2008 OECD Seoul Declaration
for the Future of the Internet Economy (OECD, 2008) and the 2011 OECD Council Recommendation on
Principles for Internet Policy Making emphasise that “effective protection of intellectual property rights
plays a vital role in spurring innovation and furthers the development of the Internet economy”
(OECD, 2011). While the global reach of the Internet has made the potential market for digital content
very large, there is a debate as to whether existing laws and regulations cope well with rapid technological
developments. Yet as the market for digital content has grown, so has the importance of implementing
sound copyright policies.
There is a diverse set of views regarding the optimisation of copyright frameworks for the Internet age
and different aspects are currently being debated at domestic and international levels. This chapter,
prepared under the direction of the OECD Committee on Digital Economy Policy (CDEP), contributes to
that debate. It describes copyright systems in a sample of diverse economies by presenting their economic
and legal settings, as well as their current mainstream policy dialogues, in a set of objective country
studies.
Scope of the chapter
This chapter presents several national experiences of how copyright frameworks have evolved in light
of the digitisation of content and the growth of the Internet, providing context with business perspectives as
well as information on the economic performance of copyright-intensive industries.
This chapter consists of three sections:
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
217 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
Section one, Copyright – An Economic Perspective, begins with an introduction to copyrights
and a summary of their economic rationale, provides an overview of key copyright industries,
and briefly sketches the existing methodologies to quantify these industries. The overview uses
the methodology developed by WIPO (2003) to classify copyright-intensive industries that was
consequently used and elaborated in by ESA-USPTO (2012) and EPO-OHIM (2013).
•
Section two, Copyright and the Internet Revolution, begins with a brief summary of
technological developments over the past 20 years. It then gives a general presentation of new
business models enabled by these technological developments and summarises the main legal
issues that appear to have become more urgent in the digital era.
•
Section three, Country studies, presents specific national experiences of how copyright has
evolved and provides insights from the perspective of various stakeholders, taking into account
national economic landscapes. Context can matter significantly; therefore the sample of
economies is as diverse and representative as practicably possible to take into account differences
among economies’ legal and economic landscapes and other factors. The following economies
have been included: Australia, Canada, Chile, Egypt, the European Union, Italy, Japan, Korea,
Poland, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and the United States.
Copyright - An Economic Perspective - Definitions and scope
Copyright is a form of intellectual property rights (IPR) that grants the creator of an original work
(creative work) certain rights over that work for a limited period of time. The copyright holder has an
exclusive right to reproduce his or her work in forms such as printed publications or sound recordings, to
distribute copies and translations, to broadcast the work or make it available, to license and/or lend it, to
adapt it (e.g. to turn a book into a screenplay) or give performances based on the work 157.
Independently from economic rights, authors are granted moral rights, such as the right of authorship,
the right of integrity of work, the right to be credited, and the right of divulgation. These rights can be
maintained by the author even if the copyright has been transferred to a third party.
Types of works that are protected under most national copyright laws include the following: literary
works (such as novels, short stories, poems, and any other fiction and non-fiction writings), dramatic
works, musical works, artistic works (whether two-dimensional as drawings, paintings etc. or threedimensional as sculptures, architectural works), maps and technical drawings (including cartographic
works, plans, blueprints, diagrams etc.), photographic works, cinematographic works, and computer
programmes and the creative aspects of databases. It should be highlighted that copyright applies to all
original works, irrespective of the quality of their content. Copyrights do not cover ideas, procedures,
methods of operation (know-how) or mathematical concepts.
Copyright protection is time-bound. Under the international agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of
Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) that is administered by the World Trade Organization (WTO),
protection should last at least 50 years after the death of the author. There is a trend for countries to adopt
longer terms than the minima required by TRIPS and the treaties administered by the World Intellectual
Property Rights Organisation (WIPO) 158, e.g. a term of the life of the author plus 70 years, or at least
70 years from first publication if the author is not a natural person.
Copyright laws have been partially standardised through a set of international conventions. The Berne
Convention was one of the first international agreements on copyright, accepted in 1886. Most of the
articles of the Berne Convention were incorporated into the World Trade Organization's TRIPS agreement
in 1995.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
218 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Today, in all economies where the Berne Convention standards apply, copyright is granted
automatically, and does not require any official certification. Once a qualifying work is presented to the
public in a physical form or secured on a medium (e.g. optical disc, computer file, painting etc.), the holder
is automatically entitled to his or her exclusive copyright. Both the Berne Convention and TRIPS prohibit
signatories from maintaining any formalities to the protection of copyright 159.
Economic rationale for copyrights
Before discussing the economic rationale for copyright, it is important to recall two key economic
properties of creative works that make them fundamentally different from tangible goods. Specifically,
creative works such as movies, books and musical compositions are non-rival and non-excludable. They
are non-rival, which means that they can be used by many persons at the same time without the individual
value of consumption being reduced. They are also non-excludable, which means that without appropriate
legal rights it is usually very difficult for the authors to prevent unauthorised uses of the content (Watt,
2004).
These economic characteristics of creative works lead to some special features of markets for creative
content. The non-rivalry of creative works, and the very low marginal cost of reproduction of most
copyrightable property, especially in the digital era, means that without legal copyright protection the work
would likely not exist (since a price close to marginal cost may not generate sufficient revenues to cover
the fixed costs of creation). Thus the argument for copyright is that an incentive to create and disseminate
must be fostered by giving the creator some control over how the creation can be used by others
(Greenhalgh and Rogers, 2010). Authorial control through exclusive rights provides important economic
incentives and gives the authors the possibility to make a living from their creative works. This in turn
allows culture and creators to mutually flourish.
The economic rationale for copyright is that without this protection, others could free ride on the
efforts of creators and hence suppress the supply of creative works. Accordingly, the lack of sufficient,
well-established and properly enforced copyrights would discourage future investments in new literary,
artistic and creative works. This clear economic rationale for copyright is well reflected in law. It is based
on the fact that “an original book, film, music composition or any other literary and artistic work is
difficult to create but easy to copy” (Raustiala and Sprigman, 2006).
The economic literature identifies an important trade-off related to copyright law: the balance between
two different effects that emerge when the cumulative aspect of creation is taken into account. On the one
hand, society needs enough protection so that, at any given moment of time, creative activities are
undertaken. On the other hand, excessive protection could create market power and thus higher access
prices, which would reduce the extent to which creative works are disseminated.
Putting it differently, if copyright protection is too strong, incentives to create are likely to be high,
but access to works may become so expensive that dissemination, in economic terms, is suboptimal. On the
other hand, if copyright protection is too weak, it is likely that too few creative works would be produced
and/or that they would be of poorer quality. Authors would choose to engage their time and effort in other
areas of activity.
As Landes and Posner (1989) summarised: “Copyright protection — the right of the copyright’s
owner to prevent others from making copies — trades off the costs of limiting access to a work against the
benefits of providing incentives to create the work in the first place. Striking the correct balance between
access and incentives is the central problem in copyright law.”
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
219 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
In this context it should be also highlighted that what is “transacted” in copyrights is the right to
access the intellectual property concerned, not the right to own the property itself. In other words,
copyright is distinct from the means of delivery. A song is protected by copyright, but a music CD is a
means of delivery. If you buy a music CD, you own that CD but you do not own the songs on it. What one
gains under a copyright transaction, therefore, is the use of the work for certain purposes or for a particular
length of time
Lastly, it has been noted by several researchers that copyright has remained one of the most pressing
areas that is lacking profound, empirical, economic studies. While some such studies do exist (e.g. EPOOHIM, 2013; ESA-USPTO, 2010; Japan Copyright Institute, 2009; Siwek-IIPA, 2004; The UK
Department for Culture, Media and Sport, 2014), they focus on the statistical aspects. More detailed
quantitative information on copyright is urgently needed to advance economic research in this area, and to
provide applicable and workable guidance to policy makers (Watt, 2004; Png, 2006; Handke, 2012).
Copyright-intensive industries
There is a distinguished history in studies that have sought to assess the importance of industries
reliant on copyright. The challenge to date has been to agree on which industries or which portion of
industries should be considered ‘copyright industries’. In practice, this has been a function of the industries
that supply work that is copyright protected and the available statistical data.
Creative work that is subject to copyright protection, as defined by TRIPS, is produced in various
parts of the economy. To facilitate the quantitative analysis of copyright-related activities in the economy,
WIPO (2003) introduced a methodology that distinguishes copyright-intensive industries and divides them
into four main groups: i) core, ii) interdependent, iii) partial, and iv) non-dedicated support.
The core copyright-intensive industries are industries that are wholly engaged in creating,
producing and manufacturing, performing, broadcasting, communicating and exhibiting, or distributing
and selling works and other protected subject matter. WIPO identified the following nine groups as core
copyright industries:
press and literature
music, theatrical productions, operas
motion picture and video
radio and television
photography
software and databases
visual and graphic arts
advertising services
copyright collective management societies.
In addition to the core copyright industries, WIPO also defines three groups of industries whose
activity is related to copyright industries to some degree: interdependent, partial, and non-dedicated
support industries.
•
Interdependent copyright industries are industries that are engaged in production, manufacture
and sale of equipment whose function is wholly or primarily to facilitate the creation, production
or use of works and other protected subject matter.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
220 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
Partial copyright industries are industries in which a portion of the activities is related to works
and other protected subject matter and may involve creation, production and manufacturing,
performance, broadcast, communication and exhibition or distribution and sales.
•
Non-dedicated support industries are industries in which a portion of the activities is related to
facilitating broadcast, communication, distribution or sales of works and other protected subject
matter, and whose activities have not been included in the core copyright industries.
Because interdependent, partial, and non-dedicated support industries are only partly engaged in
copyright-related activities, only part of their employment and value added should be considered as
copyright-intensive. To our knowledge there is no internationally agreed methodology for such exercise.
Therefore, this report focuses only on WIPO’s “core” copyright industries (Gantchev, 2004).
Two things should be kept in mind when applying the list proposed by WIPO to specific national
accounts tables. First, the WIPO definition is relatively old. Given technological progress and the evolution
of business models and industry structures since 2003, in some instances this methodology may include
industries that are no longer copyright-intensive. Consequently, some applied studies, such as those by the
ESA-USPTO (2012) and by EPO-OHIM (2013), use narrower categories of copyright-intensive industries.
For example, some activities related to the distribution of creative content, such as “wired
telecommunications activities”, and “satellite telecommunications activities”, are considered by WIPO to
be copyright-intensive, but are disregarded in the ESA-USPTO (2012) study.
Second, to be able to determine levels of employment and value added statistics for these industries, it
is necessary to identify the list of core copyright-intensive industries within local classification systems.
Even though some correspondence tables between different taxonomies can be found, in many instances
there are no straightforward equivalences between various industry classifications systems. This could be
due either to a lack of exact correspondence between the two classifications or due to different levels in the
correspondence table.
To address these issues, the final list of copyright-intensive industries is defined for each country
study separately. This is done based on the description of the ISIC codes in the WIPO (2003) study in
order to determine which local industry codes provide the closest match. For transparency reasons,
industry tables are provided at the end of each country study.
Finally, when looking at the economic impact of industries that produce, supply and distribute
copyrighted creative works, two additional things should be kept in mind. First, as noted by Thorpe (2004),
economic contribution studies are generous in that they ascribe economic contribution solely to copyright.
It should be kept in mind that some of the activity of these industries might not be necessarily related to the
copyrighted content. Second, the studies do not capture the broader cultural contributions made by
copyright works. There are broader cultural externalities, whose impact is long term.
Copyright and the Internet Revolution - The changing landscape
The recent digital revolution and the emergence of the Internet in particular have had a strong impact
on virtually all industries, including copyright-intensive industries (Kretschmer, 2012; OECD, 2013). In
the context of copyright-intensive industries two specific areas of impact deserve a closer look: i) those
elements of the Internet revolution that affect the content itself, such as content digitisation, fast transfer
and cheap storage; ii) new business models that have been enabled by these technical changes 160.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
221 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Technological revolution
Today, advanced economies tend to shift their focus from physical items to intangible assets.
Consequently, the importance of digital products grows, as they are providing a new impetus for
economies following new technological developments, creative innovations and constant infrastructure
improvements (OECD, 2012a). The three main components of this technological revolution are: (i) the
digitisation of content, (ii) the rapid growth of high-speed communications infrastructure, and (iii) a
dramatic decline in the cost of data storage.
Digitisation of content
Content digitisation is one of the main phenomena that affect the copyright-intensive industries.
Today, digital creative content enters and changes many existing creative sectors as new technological
advancements emerge. Some copyright-intensive industries use digital content as an alternative to the
physical goods they offer (e.g. music recordings, films). Others provide completely new products (e.g.
online computer games, entertainment and business software) that are uniquely digital.
The key property of digital content is its disembodied character. This results in a set of economic
characteristics that make digital content particularly different from tangible goods. These differences are
outlined in Table 5.3.
Table 5.3.
Summary of key differences between tangible goods and digital content
Product feature
Tangible goods
Digital content
Marginal cost of reproduction
Positive
Mostly zero
Hardware dependence
Limited
Hardware dependent
Digital delivery
Impossible
Possible
Market scope
Geographically limited
Global
Marginal cost of reproduction. The main consequence of the non-physical form of digital content is
its virtually negligible marginal cost of reproduction. It means that once created, digital content can be
reproduced with relatively little cost and effort. Moreover, in most cases a copy of digital content offers the
same quality as the original. In the case of a tangible product that contains some creative content (e.g. a
book or an optical disc) the reproduction involves certain positive marginal costs of supply (e.g. materials
used for production, costs of packaging, shipping etc.), and apart from its appearance may be quite
different in quality from the original.
Hardware dependence. Hardware is a necessary support for all digital content (e.g. storage on a hard
drive, optical disc, server or other device), and the potential utility that digital content offers to an end user
cannot be derived without suitable hardware. Consequently, there are strong linkages and
complementarities between hardware and digital products. In fact, trends in consumption of digital content
closely follow the newest technological developments (OECD, 2012a).
Digital delivery. The disembodied character of a digital product permits its digital delivery, for
example, via the Internet or local area networks. Possible digital delivery implies a significant reduction in
the cost of acquisition of a digital product (e.g. through reduction or elimination of searching,
transportation and storage costs) which in turn significantly facilitates the distribution process. At the same
time, digital delivery poses distinct challenges to a sustainable and secure delivery structure (see for
example: OECD, 2014).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
222 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Market scope. The extensive development of global computer networks has enabled digital products
to be instantaneously delivered to any part of the world (see e.g. BSA, 2007). This implies that the market
for digital products has a potentially global scope and many of the barriers that constrain the exchange of
physical products (e.g. costly transportation, import tariffs etc.) do not limit the exchange of digital
products.
High speed communication infrastructures
High speed fixed and mobile networks are the core of the digital economy’s infrastructure and enable
the transfer and consumption of digitised creative content. Access has improved dramatically over the past
decade (Figure 5.2) although important differences still remain between countries with regard to new highspeed network deployment (Figure 5.3.).
Figure 5.3.
Fixed broadband subscriptions per 100 inhabitants
Total and fibre/LAN; 2002-2013; OECD average
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
Figure 5.4.
Fixed broadband subscriptions per 100 inhabitants
Total and fibre/LAN, 2013
50.0
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0
0.0
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
More recently there has been substantial growth in mobile broadband access, opening up new
communication possibilities to people. Mobile broadband penetration has grown to almost 60% in the
OECD area, according to 2013 data, and seven countries (Australia, Finland, Denmark, Japan, Korea,
Sweden, the United States) now lie above the 100% penetration threshold meaning that there are some
inhabitants of these countries that have more than one mobile broadband subscription for their
smartphones, tablets and other devices (Figure 5.5.).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
223 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.5.
Mobile broadband subscriptions per 100 inhabitants
Standard mobile broadband and dedicated mobile data subscriptions, 2013
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
Mexico
Hungary
Chile
Turkey
Greece
Slovenia
Portugal
Germany
Israel
Belgium
Canada
France
Slovak Republic
Poland
Czech Republic
Switzerland
Netherlands
Italy
Austria
Spain
OECD
Ireland
Iceland
United Kingdom
Luxembourg
New Zealand
Estonia
Norway
Korea
United States
Denmark
Japan
Sweden
Finland
Australia
0
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
In 2013, the rate of mobile broadband subscriptions reached 72 subscriptions per 100 inhabitants in
the OECD area. Mobile broadband subscriptions are growing at double-digit rates and it is expected that
the number of mobile subscriptions will keep rising in the coming years, stimulated by user adoption of
multiple devices (e.g. smartphones and tablets). In terms of data traffic, Cisco (2012) estimates that the
amount generated by mobile telephones will reach almost 11 exabytes (billions of gigabytes) by 2016, i.e.
almost doubling every year (see Figure 5.6). Given that mobile phone penetration (subscriptions per
100 inhabitants) exceeds 100% in most OECD countries and that wireless broadband penetration is at
nearly 60% on average, this source of consumption of creative content data will grow significantly as smart
phones (as opposed to ordinary mobile phones) become the prevalent personal device.
Figure 5.6.
Monthly global IP traffic, 2005-16
In exabytes (billions of gigabytes)
120
Fixed Internet
Managed IP
Mobile Data
100
CAGR: 135%
80
CAGR: 42%
60
40
CAGR: 40%
20
0
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
Source: OECD (2013b) based on Cisco (2012). “Managed IP” is mostly Internet traffic within the autonomous networks of large
organisations.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
224 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Data storage
While the above-mentioned technological developments mainly drive the transport and consumption
of content, the actual use of digital creative content has been greatly facilitated by the declining cost of
storage of digitised data, including copyrighted digital content. In the past, the cost of storage discouraged
keeping content that was no longer, or unlikely to be, needed (OECD, 2011b). But storage costs have
decreased to the point at which content can generally be kept for long periods of time, if not indefinitely.
This shrinking cost of storage of digital content is illustrated, for example, by the average cost per
gigabyte of consumer hard disk drives (HDDs), which dropped from USD 56 in 1998 to USD 0.05 in 2012,
an average decline of almost 40% a year (Figure 5.7). With new generation storage technologies such as
solid-state drives (SSDs), the decline in costs per gigabyte is even faster. This means that consumers
basically do not need to take the storage issues into account when demanding digital creative content. For
suppliers it implies that their offer is no longer limited by storage costs.
Figure 5.7.
Average data storage cost for consumers, 1998-2012
In USD per gigabyte
60
HHD
56.30
SSD
50
40
40
30
CAGR 2007-12: -51%
CAGR 1998-2012: -39%
20
10
1
0.05
0
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
Note: Data for 1998-2011 are based on average prices of consumer-oriented drives (171 HDDs and 101 SSDs) from M. Komorowski
(www.mkomo.com/cost-per-gigabyte), AnandTech (www.anandtech.com/tag/storage) and Tom’s Hardware
(www.tomshardware.com/). The price estimate for SSD in 2012 is based on DeCarlo (2011) referring to Gartner.
Source: OECD based on Pingdom (2011).
Booming volume of content
The impact on content diffusion of the technological changes presented above is visible in a number
of statistics that illustrate the recent boom in on-line creative content. Examples of on-line images, songs
and videos can provide some insights. It is useful to keep in mind the difference between – and corollary
desirability of – professional content and amateur content in this context.
With respect to on-line (mostly amateur) images, the photo sharing site Flickr reached 1.6 million
photos uploaded daily on average on its platform in 2013 161. Other networks are also seeing tremendous
growth in photographic content. In September 2013, Facebook announced that its users had uploaded a
total of 250 billion pictures on the platform so far 162. Another example is Instagram, which recently
announced that its members had published 20 billion photos; on average, 60 million uploads per day 163.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
225 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Regarding commercial on-line music, the iTunes Store, one of the most popular on-line music stores,
available in 119 countries, offers a selection of over 26 million songs 164. Another on-line service, Spotify,
offers commercial music streaming services with over 20 million tracks licenced globally, and adds on
average over 20 thousand songs per day 165.
Concerning video, a good example of mostly amateur content is YouTube, one of the most popular
video sharing sites on the Internet. In mid-2014 they reported that users watch over 6 billion hours of video
each month on their platform. The site also reports that users upload 100 hours of video to YouTube every
minute 166. Film and TV content can be found on multiple download and streaming services. One example
is Netflix, whose streaming-on-demand platform is reported to offer over ten thousand movies and TV
titles on the US market 167. In Europe, the MAVISE database organised by the EU’s Office for
Harmonisation in the Internal Market (OHIM) has identified 3695 on-demand services 168.
These examples highlight only the technology-enabled growth in volume of content, and do not take
into account content quality. However, irrespective of the quality aspect, one should admit that such large
volumes can be observed only on the Internet and are not attainable in the “off-line world”.
New business models
Continuous developments in technological infrastructure, software solutions and hardware
significantly improve market access and affect business innovation processes. As technology continues to
evolve, improve and expand, more and more services introduce new business models, while other services
offer combinations of traditional business models. Key innovations in recent years include the expansion of
business models that:
•
are based on the Internet as a new way of content delivery;
•
take advantage of improved portability of content thanks to growing penetration of mobile
devices such as smartphones or tablets, and
•
adapted traditional ways of generating revenue from off-line to on-line models, such as ad-based
models and subscription-based models.
In addition to the general discussion of new business models presented below, brief case studies of
relevant individual business models will be discussed in the country studies section.
New delivery models
Rights holders have recognised that the Internet is a fast and convenient way to deliver content.
Download and streaming services provide a variety of options to consumers, offering digital recorded
content which can include individual music tracks, albums, TV episodes, special premium content, and
videos etc. for purchase or streaming via computer, mobile phone or tablet, through a variety of delivery
models. These services are present in virtually all sectors of the copyright-intensive industry, including
audio visual works (e.g. TV and film), music, publishing, professional photography and video games.
Recorded music was the first copyright-intensive industry to confront the physical-to-digital
transition. Even though the music industry in some countries (e.g. Canada) has been reporting declines of
sales since the 2000s, more recently retailers have reported growth in sales volumes and in the
geographical scope of their markets 169. For example, in 2012 there were 2.3 billion single track downloads
worldwide, an increase of 8% over 2011, and 210 million digital albums sold, up 16% over 2011 (IFPI,
2013). Another example is the iTunes store that was launched in 2003 in the US and it was followed by
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
226 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Canada and several EU countries in 2004. Today the iTunes store with music is available in more than 150
countries.
In book publishing, digital technologies have been employed for a long time, but they took off only
when end users were offered a satisfying reading experience. This happened in the past five years, after the
introduction of sophisticated e-reading devices (See Box 5.1.).
Box 5.1. e-Books
The e-book is a book composed in or converted to digital format for display on a computer screen or handheld
device.
Figures collected to date by national publishers associations suggest that e-book sales still make up only a small
proportion (around 1% for 2010) of book sales in most OECD countries outside the United States. Figures for the
United Kingdom suggest a slightly greater percentage of the book market represented by e-books (2-3%). Figures
for the United States show e-books representing up to 8% of book sales in 2010. However, more notable than
absolute revenue or percentage figures, are the recent dramatic rates of growth in OECD markets for e-books. On
19 May, 2011, Amazon announced that since April its sales of e-books had overtaken sales of all forms of print
books combined. Starting in April it has sold 105 e-books for every 100 print books. This does not include
downloads of free Kindle e-books, which if counted, push the e-book advantage even higher. Consumers spent
an estimated USD 966 million on e-books in 2010. By 2015, the industry is anticipated to nearly triple to almost
USD 3 billion.
There are a number of indications that e-books are not replacing demand for print books in the general “trade”, or
“consumer” category. While there is insufficient data available at this stage to draw any concrete conclusions on
trends, some of the recent figures from the industry indicate that e-books are stimulating demand for print books.
Contrary to widespread belief, the publishing industry in the United States grew in both 2009 and 2010, aided by
USD 1.6 billion in sales from e-books. Total estimated revenue for all US publishers rose 3.1% in 2010, to USD
27.9 billion, following a 2.5% increase in 2009. E-book sales across all publishing categories in the United States
rose 29.4% in 2009 and 38.9% in 2010, and accounted for 5.8% of total industry revenue in 2010.
Source: OECD (2012b)
Visual arts are another sector where the technical possibility of digital downloads has profoundly
reshaped existing business models and provided corollary opportunities for piracy. Today, online services,
mainly websites and other platforms such as newsgroups, are frequently used to disseminate visual arts. In
addition, the Internet also enabled the emergence of dedicated on-line databases containing specialised arts
images. Sometimes images are disseminated without charge (e.g. Google images) or for a given fee
through photo stock agencies (NMR, Roger Viollet, Corbis, Magnum, etc.) and microstocks (Getty Images,
Fotolia, etc.) One potential difficulty for visual artists, however, has been the ease with which identifying
metadata and other important information can be stripped from works in the online environment. This
problem exacerbates the obstacles affecting visual artists’ efforts to protect and license their works.
The video game industry is another industry segment where the Internet acts as an efficient means of
content delivery. Over the past several years, online games have become one of the fastest growing
segments of the video game sector, spurred by rising broadband penetration and the inclusion of robust
online capabilities in the current generation of consoles. Legitimate downloads of all types of games are
widely provided by game publishers, as well as console and phone manufacturers. Today, the video game
industry is characterised by the very large numbers of players who are able to simultaneously engage with
each other and to play online. A 2013 study conducted for the industry revealed that 72% of gamers in the
United States played some form of online game. This represents an increase in incidence of 5 percentage
points among gamers from 2012 (NPD Group, 2013).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
227 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Improved portability
Improved portability is another area where technological progress affects business models in the
copyright-intensive industries. Portable devices such as laptops, smartphones and tablets give users more
opportunities to consume creative content delivered over the Internet (streamed or downloaded). In fact,
according to a recent study, an average European has 2.6 screens against 1.4 three years ago (Let’s Go
Connected, 2013).
Improved portability is recognised by copyright-intensive industries that now offer services that work
on all types of mobile devices, such as smartphones or tablets. These services provide streaming, cached
content (temporarily downloaded to a device so users can listen even when offline), tracks, albums, videos
and ringtones for use on mobile phones. Streaming services allow users to choose and listen to whatever
music they like, on the go, while the caching of music means that it is possible to look through all playlists
and load up favourites. Downloaded purchased tracks on mobile phones can also be transferred to other
devices.
This category also includes mobile applications or 'apps' that work in conjunction with other
complementary online services on an Internet-connected PC. Mobile games are a case in point (see
Box 5.2.).
Box 5.2. Mobile games
Games is now the largest category of apps on Apple's iOS App Store, and game publishers regularly
constitute the majority of the top ten app publishers on both the iOS App Store and the Google Play store,
measured by revenue. Of the 20 most downloaded apps on the iOS platform (as of 7 June 2013), 12 were games,
and of the 20 highest grossing apps, 15 were games. Games now claim 80% of the revenues on Google Play and
75% on iOS. In the second quarter of 2013, games accounted for roughly 45% of downloads from the iOS App
store.
The business model for mobile games is moving from the pay to download to the so-called freemium mode,
where games are downloaded for free, with micro-transactions and advertising providing revenues. It is estimated
that in-game purchases will soon outpace download fees.
The mobile game market is expected to continue to grow as the penetration by smartphones and tablets
expands. More people are playing games, including casual games, social games, and more-advanced multiplayer
games. Simple, arcade-style games that involve puzzles, words, board and card games, game show and trivia
continue to dominate the market because they are quick to learn and easy to play. The most popular mobile
games are single-player board games, puzzles, and word games.
New sources of revenue
Over the past decade copyright-intensive industries have experimented with different revenue
schemes in order to profit from digital consumption. These schemes vary from a total “paywall”, where no
content can be accessed without payment, to models where the whole content is available for free and the
revenue is gathered from other sources, such as advertisements.
An illustrative example of a “paywall” can be found in the music industry, where there are numerous
subscription based services. These services offer access to their entire catalogue to customers for a monthly
fee. Many subscription services also come bundled with either an Internet or a mobile phone subscription.
Other subscription services offer selected bundles of tracks or music albums for smaller subscription fees,
or offer subscriptions on a daily or weekly basis, according to consumer preferences.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
228 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Subscription services are the fastest growing area in video and in digital music. In 2013 there were
about 2500 video-on-demand services ago (Let’s Go Connected, 2013). In digital music, there were at least
530 music subscription services in 2013 in the EU only (Enders, 2013). The rapid growth of subscription
based services was largely driven by bundling deals with Internet Service Providers (ISPs) and mobile
operators, an improved user experience, integration with social networks and a greater variety of price
points.
In addition to the subscription-based services, where a payment is necessary to get access to the
content, another observable trend is towards introducing a metered model, where copyright-intensive
industries charge for access to certain content or services while also allowing casual visitors a certain
amount of access. This strategy allows developing long-term paying customers, while also benefiting from
the potential advertising revenue generated by visits by more spontaneous users. For example, in the news
industry the Financial Times website, FT.com, only allows access to registered users and subscribers, and
registered (but non-paying) users can only read up to ten articles per month. In addition, an online
subscription provides many services, such as the ability to comment on articles, to write blog posts, have a
personalised home page, and to have access to archives. These services provide readers with additional
reasons to pay for subscriptions, while allowing others simply to peruse the news pages freely.
In a different approach, many services offer a free advertising-supported model where consumers sign
up to a service and benefit from most of its functions, yet listen to (or watch) a certain number of ads. Most
operators of ad-supported streaming models as well as the copyright owners whose works are being
consumed hope to convert users to premium versions which offer additional functions and ad-free services.
Focus on legal frameworks
Copyright is a legal concept that is more than three centuries old, has been evolving over that time,
and is codified in a set of international treaties 170, although the pace of development of the international
regime has recently tended to slow down. The recent technological revolution and its impact on creative
content significantly re-shaped the environment addressed by copyrights. Consequently, certain legal
aspects might need re-visiting and some countries have amended or attempt to amend them. The analysis
of various national experiences (presented in section four) distils five general areas of copyright legislation
that have been the subject of discussion in the context of the Internet. They include:
•
copyright limitations and exceptions
•
scope of copyrights
•
orphan works
•
copyright enforcement
•
copyright registration
There is a diverse set of views regarding the optimisation of these areas and different ways of dealing
with these legal aspects are presented in the country studies section. That presentation is neither exhaustive
nor is it necessarily universally representative; it presents those legal issues that were identified as relevant
in most of the twelve analysed country studies. Clearly, in some economises there might be other
copyright-related legal issues that are being currently debated in the context of the Internet revolution.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
229 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Limitations and exceptions
The technology-enabled ease of copying and transforming content calls for adequate legal solutions in
this area. As noted in the Hargreaves Review, the copyright licensing process in the digital age can be
overly expensive, difficult to use and access, insufficiently transparent, etc. (Hargreaves, 2011). According
to the report it took nearly five years to the BBC to assemble the rights necessary to launch its popular
iPlayer service. Such large cost of time and money that can be often borne by the industry becomes
discouraging for individual users. Consequently, the technology enabled ease of copying and transforming
content calls for legal frameworks that minimise these monetary and non-monetary transactions costs,
especially in the area of small-scale, personal use.
Collective management organisations can be useful in bringing transaction costs down so that right
holders can more easily manage their collections of content. Other flexible licensing arrangements such as
micro-licensing and sublicensing can also create enhanced efficiency, as can effective databases that
provide ownership and other information.
Another example of situations for which policy makers have introduced limitations and exceptions is
where public benefits, or what economists call positive externalities, may be associated with copying
copyrighted content. For example, specific and limited exemptions for the use of copyrighted material have
been implemented for the purpose of research or study, judicial proceedings, parody or satire, and criticism
or review.
Scope
Copyright may apply to a wide range of creative, intellectual, or artistic forms, or "works". Specifics
vary by jurisdiction, but these can include poems, theses, plays and other literary works, motion pictures,
choreography, musical compositions, sound recordings, live performances, paintings, drawings, sculptures,
photographs, computer software, radio and television broadcasts, and industrial designs.
In the context of technological progress it is important to notice the issues related to data-protection
by copyrights. Economic and social activities have long relied on data. Today, however, the technology has
enabled a shift towards a data-driven socioeconomic model, in which data are a core asset that can create a
significant competitive advantage and drive innovation, sustainable growth and development (OECD,
2013b). Data can be created by either people or machines (such as sensors gathering climate information,
satellite imagery, digital pictures and videos, purchase transaction records, GPS signals, etc.). It is
generated in many sectors of the economy, from healthcare to transport and energy, and stored in
databases.
In the context of copyrights, it is necessary to distinguish between creative and non-creative databases
because a different set of legal rules applies to each of them. Generally, legal systems protect creative
databases that constitute a creative compilation under copyright law. Non-creative databases are those that
do not include a component that could be considered creative and original, even though their creation
required a certain level of effort or investment. However, the level of creativity required for copyright
protection that makes the difference between a creative and non-creative database has not been defined
internationally.
In addition, some countries grant legal protection for non-creative databases either through including
them in their copyright legislation or by sui generis right (special right) to protect non-creative databases
that do not meet the required level of creativity for copyright protection but which were made with
substantial investment.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
230 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Orphan works
Orphan works have been referred to as copyrighted works whose rights holder cannot be identified
and/or located after a thorough search 171.
The phenomenon of orphan works is not new, but the advent of new technologies has brought this
issue to the forefront. Given the global nature of the Internet network and the booming volume of
copyrighted content available online, an identification of the legitimate right holder of a particular
copyrighted item often becomes impossible. As highlighted in a report prepared for the British Film
Institute (BFI), the fact that “it is sometimes impossible to identify or locate the rights holder means that
archives, libraries, museums, broadcasters, commercial operators and other media providers cannot ask for
permission to make use of the orphan work and therefore digitisation projects and online access are
hindered. Orphan works therefore remain unavailable to the general public, entombed in public or private
archives, and new business models are hampered from making use of them” (KEA, 2011). An illustrative
example is the development of digital libraries, which have a key role in preserving the copyrighted works
and that are hampered by inability of identification of some of the copyrighted material (Iglesias, 2009).
Enforcement
The rapid development of the Internet implies that more people than ever before have access to
practically any type of news or data. However, this technological progress also facilitates digital piracy, as
users employ various web based workarounds and applications to distribute and exchange large amounts of
pirated digital products instantaneously around the world. Hence, a significant volume of digital piracy
occurs via the Internet, which is the main way to exchange of all types of digital information (OECD,
2009).
Piracy over the Internet is a significant problem that seems to be growing in many countries.
According to the recent 301 Report by the US Trade Representative, on-line copyright infringement is a
growing concern for virtually all copyright-intensive industries, in all formats including mobile telephones,
tablets, flash drives, and other mobile technologies. In addition, some new forms of piracy emerge such as
so-called “grey shards” (pirate servers). These servers offer players of cloud-based entertainment software
unauthorised access to play copyrighted games. This access is generated through hacked software or
circumvention of technological protection measures (USTR, 2014).
The local legal and regulatory frameworks are key factors in preventing digital piracy. Legal systems
allow copyright holders to take legal action against infringing parties and to claim compensation for
potential losses. A strong legal framework can reduce digital piracy, while a weak one could be viewed as
tolerant towards these activities and allows piracy to flourish. This hypothesis seems to be confirmed by
several studies by, that found that economies with strong copyright protection regimes tended to report
lower rates of piracy (Van Kranenburg and Hogenbirk, 2003; Das, Mukhopadhyay and Bagchi, 2014).
However, legal frameworks are effective only to the extent that the laws are enforced in practice. If
the resources devoted to enforcement are inadequate or intellectual property rights are not otherwise
enforced by public authorities, then the value of the nominal laws and regulations to the rights holders is
low. Even the nominally strictest law could therefore potentially have no impact on the scale of digital
piracy.
In addition, the risk of discovery and subsequent legal action must also be considered in relation to the
potential consequences that infringers may face, in terms of the amount of any expected monetary penalty
or the likelihood and duration of possible jail sentences. For instance, if the expected consequences are
small, then even a high risk of discovery may have little practical impact on counterfeiting and piracy
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
231 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
activity (OECD, 2009). In fact, there is a significant difference, for instance, between a minor fine, and a
criminal prosecution that eventually could result even in a prison sentence. In fact, according to a study by
BSA – Harris (2007) potential legal consequences could discourage some individuals from exchanging
pirated digital goods.
As a practical matter, digital piracy generally cannot be detected at national borders. The international
flow of pirated digital products is more difficult to track by law enforcement agencies from sellers, via
distributors, to producers, than the flow of physical goods. The large numbers of individuals involved
present further challenges for effective international cooperation amongst enforcement agencies.
Copyright registration
The purpose of copyright registration is to place on record a verifiable account of the date, owner and
content of the work in question, so that in the event of a legal claim, or case of infringement or plagiarism,
the copyright owner can produce a copy of the work from an official government source. In this context
copyright registration could be also seen as one of the potential solutions to the issue of orphan works.
According to some researchers the currently observed increase in orphan works can be largely attributed to
the fact that that copyright is automatically granted without any registration process (Netanel, 2008).
Registering a copyright should not be confused with granting a copyright. According to the Berne
Convention (1886), copyright applies as soon as the work is published; registration does not strengthen or
modify the copyright in any way.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
232 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
COUNTRY STUDIES
Australia
State of the Internet
In recent years access to broadband networks and the Internet has constantly increased in Australia.
In terms of fixed broadband, penetration levels have been growing constantly and are slightly below the
OECD average, reaching 26 subscriptions per 100 inhabitants in 2013. In addition, further deployments of
fibre networks have taken place. Overall, however, deployment of fibre is still at an early stage in Australia
and is below the OECD average (see Figure 5.8.).
Figure 5.8.
Broadband penetration rates in Australia
2002-2013, per 100 inhabitants
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Australia)
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Australia)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
More recently there has been rapid and substantial growth in mobile broadband access in Australia,
opening up new communication possibilities to people as they are away from a fixed-line connection.
Mobile broadband penetration has recently exceeded 100% in Australia, meaning that some customers
have more than one mobile internet subscription (Figure 5.9.).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
233 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.9.
Mobile broadband subscriptions in Australia
2009-2013, per 100 inhabitants
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
2009-Q4
2010-Q2
2010-Q4
2011-Q2
2011-Q4
Australia
2012-Q2
2012-Q4
2013-Q2
2013-Q4
OECD
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
Value added: Over the past ten years copyright-intensive industries in Australia have demonstrated
overall satisfactory performance 172. Between 2002 and 2011 the total volume of the copyright-based
industries grew by 9%, at a much slower rate than the overall economy which grew by more than 50%
during the same period. In absolute terms Australian copyright-intensive industries reported moderate rates
of growth in the period 2001-2007, followed by a slow decline between 2008 and 2010. In 2012 the total
contribution calculated for the core copyright-based industries was AUD 67.5 billion, accounting for 5% of
Australia’s GDP (Figure 5.10).
Figure 5.10.
Added value of copyright-Intensive industries in Australia
2002-2012, AUD million (right axis) and % of GDP (left axis)
10%
74,000
72,000
70,000
68,000
66,000
64,000
62,000
60,000
58,000
56,000
9%
8%
7%
6%
5%
4%
3%
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
% GDP
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
Value added
Source: PWC (2012) and Australian Bureau of Statistics, Australian Industry.
Employment: The total number of people employed in copyright-intensive industries represented
5.5% of all employed. Between 2002 and 2011, the overall share of people employed in copyrightintensive industries in total industry employees reported a slight reduction by one percentage point. The
total employment reported some fluctuations over that period. In 2011 it amounted to 610,000, which was
slightly more than the volume of employment in these industries in 2002 (Figure 5.11).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
234 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.11.
Employment in copyright-intensive industries
% of total employment (right axis) and total volume of employment (left axis)
7%
640,000
6%
630,000
5%
620,000
4%
610,000
3%
600,000
2%
590,000
1%
580,000
0%
570,000
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
% of total employment
2008
2009
2010
2011
Employed
Source: PWC (2012) and Australian Bureau of Statistics, Australian Industry.
Copyright-intensive industries and the Internet economy: The Internet profoundly re-shapes
Australian industry by re-shaping existing business models and introducing brand new ways of business
operation. According to existing estimates the broadly interpreted Internet economy contributed directly in
2010 AUD 50 billion to Australian GDP, which is 3.6% of total GDP of Australia (Deloitte 2011).
Australian copyright-intensive industries successfully leverage the technical opportunities offered by
the Internet. For example in 2011 JB HiFi, the largest Australian music, video and games retailer
introduced a web-based, platform agnostic streaming music service JB Hi-Fi NOW. Within six months
after the launch JAB HiFi NOW has managed to achieve a very competitive position. For example, the
daily iOS rankings for free Music apps on the Australian iTunes store shows JB Hi-Fi NOW app
downloads consistently in the top 10-20 positions. According to Scott Browning, the marketing director at
JB Hi-Fi the most important factor was “the cost of broadband, and the speed of download, [whereas]
copyright laws don’t impede JB Hi-Fi plans; in fact they help by providing a platform to build from.”
In addition, there are several start-ups that took the advantage of the internet as the distribution
channel. Examples include Atlassian (software) and Quickflix (television and film content) (See Box 5.3.).
Box 5.3. Australian creative businesses on the Internet: Atlassian, Quickflix
Atlassian is a worldwide leader in software development. Founded in 2002 it is well known for its tracking
applications and team collaboration products. Currently its customers include: Boeing, Ikea, Cisco, Nike and
Sony. It should be noted that instead of having traditional sales unit, Atlassian fully relies on the Internet as a sole
sales platform team, and presents all prices, products information, support requests, as well as training materials
and documentation on its web-site.
Quickflix is Australia’s leading online movie company. It offers subscriptions to television shows and movies
delivered as DVDs by mail or streamed instantly over broadband networks. Customers stream content via the
internet, direct to their preferred viewing device, It has amassed a collection of more than 60,000 movie and
television series titles and as of June 2013, had over 106,000 customers.
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: In Australia the legal issue of copyrights is regulated by the
Copyright Act that was first passed in 1968 and amended several times.
Recent evolution: The Copyright Act 1968 framework was designed well before digital technology
became a prevalent feature across society. A number of amendments have sought to bring the Act up to
date with contemporary uses of technology. Many of these technologies have facilitated access to goods
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
235 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
and services produced by copyright-related industries. Since 1968, there have been over 60 major or minor
amendments to the Act. The most recent significant amendment to the Act was made in 2006 (Copyright
Amendment Act 2006). Among other things, this amendment strengthened the anti-circumvention laws
(against bypassing technical protection measures of content), and re-examined the issue of copyright
exceptions, but it did not enable for personal copying of digital content, which was becoming a common
practice at the time.
Duration of copyright: In Australia copyright protection generally ends 70 years following the death
of the last living author 173.
Institutional setting: There is no copyright office in Australia. The two main institutions in the area
of copyrights in Australia are: Attorney-General’s Department and the Copyright Tribunal of Australia.
•
The Attorney-General’s Department of the Government of Australia administers the Copyright
Act 1968. Within the Department, the Commercial and Administrative Law Branch, is
responsible for developing copyright policy. The Attorney-General’s Department consults a
number of other agencies where necessary, including: the Department of Foreign Affairs and
Trade, the Department of Communications, and the Department of Education amongst others.
•
The Copyright Tribunal of Australia is an independent body administered by the Federal Court of
Australia. It has jurisdiction with respect to licensing of copyright works.
Database protection: There is no sui generis database right in Australia. Databases that meet
originality criterion are protected by copyrights.
Limitations and exceptions: The main concept of exceptions to copyright infringement in Australia
is called “fair dealing”. Fair dealing defines the scope of use of a copyrighted work that does not require a
right holder’s permission. In Australia fair dealing covers: non-commercial research and study purposes,
review and criticism, parody and satire, "reporting the news", judicial proceedings or professional advice.
In addition special exceptions in some cases are provided for libraries, archives, educational institutions,
and persons with a disability.
Orphan works: There are no general exceptions for using orphan works in Australia. Potential users
of creative content who cannot identify the copyright owner are advised to use a risk management
approach 174.
Copyright registration: No registration is necessary for copyright protection in Australia
Enforcement: In Australia copyright infringement is generally a civil matter, which the copyright
owner must pursue in court. Under certain circumstances, the infringement may also constitute a criminal
misdemeanour or felony. In addition a notice in writing may be given to the Chief Executive Officer of
Customs objecting to the importation of copies of copyright materials suspected to be infringing copies.
Current debate
Summary of current debate: The public debate on “copyrights in the age of the Internet” is
relatively advanced in Australia. It has been taking place for several years, and gathered numerous experts
from the government, academia, think tanks, industry and civil society.
With respect to public agencies, the Australian Law Reform Commission is a federal agency that
reviews Australia’s laws. It has recently published its report, “Copyright and the Digital Economy” that
recommends the Government to introduce a fair use exception, relax statutory licensing provisions, and
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
236 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
reassess the effectiveness of the retransmission scheme, amongst other things 175. The Government is
currently considering the ALRC’s recommendations.
In addition, on 14 February 2014, the Attorney-General, Senator the Hon George Brandis, announced
that the Government would be looking to address the issue of online piracy. This is likely to re-open the
public debate in Australia on the general issues of secondary liability.
Industry associations and industry best practices: There are numerous industry associations in
copyright-intensive industries in Australia. The main ones include: Australian Screen Directors Authorship
Collecting Society (ASDAC), Australian Writers Guild Authorship Collecting Society (AWGACS),
Copyright Agency Limited, Media, Entertainment & Arts Alliance, Music Rights Australia, Phonographic
Performance Company of Australia (PPCA), Screenrights, Viscopy, Copyright Society of Australia, and
the Australian Copyright Council.
These associations carry out a number of activities, including: collective rights management
(ASDAC, AWGACS, PPCA, and Viscopy), countering copyright infringement (intelligence collection,
collaboration with relevant enforcement authorities, training of public authorities), awareness raising
campaigns in the area of copyrights, and data collection.
Previous governments have sought to facilitate a self-regulatory code for internet service providers
and rights-holders to deal with the issue of online copyright infringement and authorisation. The Australian
industry has so far been unable to reach agreement on how such a code would work in practice with the
main point of disagreement being who would bear the costs of any potential scheme.
Canada
State of the Internet
In recent years access to broadband networks and the Internet has constantly increased in Canada.
In terms of fixed broadband, penetration levels have been growing constantly and are well above the
OECD average, reaching maturity. In addition, further deployments of fibre networks have taken place.
Adoption of fibre/LAN subscription in Canada is still at an early stage and is below the OECD average
(see Figure 5.12). Canadian operators more typically upgraded their networks via hybrid-fibre FTTN and
cable DOCSIS 3.0 technologies. Overall coverage of networks at speeds of at least 30 Megabits per second
reached 80% of households in 2013 176.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
237 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.12.
Broadband penetration rates in Canada
2002-2013, per 100 inhabitants
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Canada)
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Canada)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
More recently there has been rapid and substantial growth in mobile broadband access in Canada,
opening up new communication possibilities to people as they are away from a fixed-line connection.
Mobile broadband penetration has exceeded 40% in 2012 and has grown to almost 50% in Canada in 2013.
However, this is still below the OECD average that reached close to 60% (Figure 5.13) in 2013.
Figure 5.13.
Mobile broadband subscriptions in Canada
2009-2013, per 100 inhabitants
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
2009-Q4
2010-Q2
2010-Q4
2011-Q2
2011-Q4
Canada
2012-Q2
2012-Q4
2013-Q2
2013-Q4
OECD
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
Copyright-based industries: Market overview
Value added: Between 2003 and 2012, Canada’s core copyright-based industries have demonstrated
performance comparable to the overall economy of Canada 177. The contribution of the copyright-based
industries to the Canadian GDP has increased by 15.9%, from CAD 36.8 billion in 2003 to CAD 42.6
billion in 2012. During the same period, Canadian GDP has increased by more than 18.5%. Furthermore,
in terms of percentage contribution to the GDP, the share of core copyright-based industries in Canadian
GDP has remained relatively constant around 2.84% on average during the period 2003 to 2012
(Figure 5.14).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
238 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.14.
Added value of core copyright-based industries in Canada, 2003-2012
3.20%
50
3.10%
3.00%
38.8
38.2
36.8
40.6
42.4
2.80%
43.2
42.3
42.6
45
40
2.91%
2.84%
2.83%
2.82%
2.80%
42.7
2.97%
2.89%
2.90%
43.1
35
2.82%
2.78%
2.74%
2.70%
30
25
2003
2005
2004
2006
% of GDP (left axis)
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
Core Copyright-Based Industries (right axis in CAD billion)
Source: Statistics Canada's key socioeconomic database (CANSIM 379-0031); for core copyright-based industries see Table 5.1.
Employment: Based on Statistics Canada Survey of Employment, Payrolls and Hours (SEPH), corecopyright based industries are found to be responsible for 2.9% of total employment in Canada in 2012,
estimated at 447,226 jobs. Over the last ten years (2003-2012), the total number of people employed in
copyright-based industries has increased by nearly 11.2% in comparison to more than 13.5% for the entire
economy. Figure 5.15 below provides detailed description of the evolution of the level of employment in
the copyright-based industries.
Figure 5.15.
Employment in copyright-based industries in Canada, 2003-2012
460
449.6
441.5
Thousands
440
3.6%
3.4%
403.0
402.0
395.0
400
3.2%
3.0%
380
2.9%
2003
3.8%
439.2
415.8
420
360
440.8
432.0
447.2
2004
2.9%
2005
3.0%
3.0%
2007
2008
3.0%
3.0%
3.0%
2010
2011
2.9%
2006
Employment in copyright-based occupations (left axis)
2009
2.9%
2012
3.0%
2.8%
% of totel employment in Canada (right axis)
Source: Statistics Canada's key socioeconomic database (CANSIM 281-0024); for core copyright-based industries see Table 5.1.
International exchange: International payments made and received was in a negative trade balance
over the ten-year period observed for copyright and related rights services. Annual receipts increased by
more than 45.4% between 2003 and 2012 from CAD 295 million to CAD 429 million. On the other hand,
payments also grew by more than 120.9% over that period from CAD 561 million to 1,239 million CAD.
(Figure 5.16.).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
239 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.16.
International Payments and Receipts in Copyright-Based Industry Services, Copyright and
Related Rights, 2003 to 2012
Source: Statistics Canada's key socioeconomic database (CANSIM 376-0033).
Copyright-intensive industries and the Internet economy: Canadian copyright-intensive industries
successfully leverage the technical opportunities offered by the Internet. The percentage of firms selling
online is the highest in the information and cultural sector, at (35% in 2012) and in arts, entertainment and
recreation industry sector (25.5% in 2012) 178. At industry-level, there are several copyright-intensive
industries that provide data that highlight the importance of the Internet as a medium of distribution of
digital content in Canada. For example, for the music industry, the on-line sales revenues of recordings
climbed from CAD 79.0 million in 2009 to CAD 92.4 million in 2011. Nevertheless, this did not offset the
drop in sales of compact discs over the same period. Compact disc sales fell to CAD 195.1 million in 2011
from CAD 290.3 million in 2009. Total sales of recordings declined by 19.8% from 2009 to 2011,
reflecting significant drops in sales by Canadian and non-Canadian artists 179. For video games, online sales
accounted for about a third of all revenue in 2013 180. For the publishing industry, there is substantial
evidence for growing consumer demand for e-books in Canada. According to some recent studies, 20% of
book-buyers bought one or more e-books in 2013, up from 18% in 2012 181.
This growth in on-line sales was paralleled by emergence of numerous start-ups that took the
advantage of the internet as a distribution channel. Examples include the companies Stingray Digital
(music), Kobo (publishing), and the website Têtes à claques (TV) (See Box 5.4.).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
240 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Box 5.4. Canadian creative businesses on the Internet: Stingray Digital, Kobo, Frima Studio, Têtes à
claques.
Stingray Digital Group is a media and entertainment company that focuses on interactive music
broadcasting and distribution. The group has several services in its portfolio, including an interactive Internet
service offering karaoke services, provision of subscription music services for businesses, and several digital pay
TV and video-on-demand services. Founded in 2007, Stingray Digital Group reported a very high growth over the
past years, including successful entries on the US and UK markets.
Kobo is the producer of Kobo eReader, the most popular e-book reader in Canada. In addition to hardware
production, in July 2012 Kobo launched Kobo Writing Life, a platform that allows authors to direct self-publish
their work, avoiding intermediaries.
Têtes à claques is a French-language comedy website. It was created in 2006, and today it is one of the
most popular francophone websites in Canada. Following the series' success, its author, Michel Beaudet, has
established a dedicated website to commercialisation of the characters that appear in Têtes à claques in (for
example) ad campaigns, labels of commercial products, etc.
Sources: www.stingraydigital.com, www.kobo.com, www.tetesaclaques.tv
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: In Canada the legal issue of copyrights is regulated by the Copyright
Act of Canada that was first passed in 1921 and amended several times.
Recent evolution: In 1997 Canada introduced into its legislation neighbouring rights protections for
performers and producers of sound recordings, a statutory damages regime, new copyright exceptions and
limitations and implemented the Rome Convention for the Protection of Performers, Producers of
Phonograms and Broadcasting Organizations.
In 2007, the federal government passed Bill C-59, the Unauthorised Recording of a Movie Act, which
amended the Criminal Code to prohibit the recording of a movie in a movie theatre without the theatre
owner’s consent, with an increased possible sentence if the act was committed for commercial purposes.
The most recent amendment was the Copyright Modernization Act in 2012. Among other objectives,
it implements the World Intellectual Property Organization’s 1996 Internet Treaties. The rationale for these
amendments was to provide a copyright framework that is forward-looking and flexible, that will help spur
creation and innovation, and that supports new business models in the digital age. It also aimed to provide
rights holders with new rights and tools for the digital environment, while giving individuals greater
flexibility in using legitimately acquired materials and creating user-generated content.
For example, the new provisions promote creativity, innovation, and legitimate business models, and
strengthen the ability of copyright owners to control the uses of their online works in order to prevent
widespread illicit use. Such provisions include legal protection for rights management information and a
new category of civil liability that targets those who enable online piracy. Copyright owners may choose to
apply technological protection measures (TPMs), such as digital locks, to prevent unauthorised access to
copyrighted material benefit from new protection against circumvention, or breaking locks. New rules also
prevent the manufacture, importation, and sale of devices that can break digital locks. Software producers,
video game and movie distributors, for example, rely on digital locks as part of their business model to
protect the investment they make in developing products.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
241 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Duration of copyright: For works, copyright protection generally ends 50 years following the death
of the last living author. For sound recordings, performances, non-dramatic cinematographic works, and
anonymous works, copyright protection generally ends 50 years following the year of first publication. For
communication signals, copyright protection ends 50 years following the year they were broadcasted.
Institutional setting: The two main institutions in the area of copyrights in Canada include: the
Copyright Office and the Copyright Board.
The Copyright Act provides that the Copyright Office shall be attached to the Patent Office (which is
part of the Canadian Intellectual Property Office). The functions of the Copyright Office are: i) to register
copyrights and assignments and licences of copyright, and ii) to maintain the Register of Copyrights. The
Office also provides very general information on the subject of copyright in Canada, but does not provide
advisory or mediation services.
The Copyright Board is an independent, quasi-judicial tribunal that acts as an economic regulatory
body. Under the Copyright Act, the Board is empowered to establish (either mandatorily or at the request
of an interested party) the royalties to be paid for the use of copyrighted works when the administration of
such copyright is entrusted to a collective-administration society. The Board also has the right to supervise
agreements between users and licensing bodies, and issues licences when the copyright owner cannot be
located.
Database protection: There is no sui generis protection of databases in Canada. Databases that meet
the requirements for copyright protection are treated under copyright law like any other work. The
definition of “compilation” in Canada explicitly includes “a work resulting from the selection or
arrangement of data.” In addition, databases can be also protected by legislation on unfair competition and
trade secrets.
Limitations and exceptions: In addition to various specific exceptions to copyright infringement that
are tailored to particular uses in certain contexts, the Copyright Act includes a general exception to engage
in “fair dealing” with copyright material, provided that it is undertaken in respect of one of a limited
number of enumerated purposes (namely: research or private study; criticism or review; news reporting;
education; and satire and parody), and provided that the use in question is “fair”. Whether a dealing is
“fair” depends on a series of criteria set out by the courts, including the purpose of the dealing, the
character of the dealing, the amount of the dealing, the nature of the work, available alternatives to the
dealing and the effect of the dealing on the market of the work.
Orphan works: Section 77 of Canada’s Copyright Act comprises a supplemental licensing scheme
for orphan works. In order to get a licence, an applicant must demonstrate that "reasonable efforts” to
locate copyright holders were made. The licence is issued by the Copyright Board of Canada and is only
valid in Canada for a specified amount of time and typically involves a royalty payment (either upfront to a
collective society or to an owner if one emerges).
Copyright registration: Copyright registration is not required in Canada, although it confers certain
procedural benefits in cases of copyright infringement. The cost of copyright registration is CAD 50 for an
application filed online and CAD 65 for an application filed by any other means. To register a copyright,
the applicant must submit an application form that includes information, including the name and address of
the owner of the copyright; a declaration; the category of work; the title of the work; the name of the
author.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
242 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Enforcement: Canada’s IP enforcement agencies are the following:
The Royal Canadian Mounted Police (RCMP), the Canadian national police service, is responsible for
enforcing intellectual property rights, including offences for copyright infringement. Criminal cases
investigated as a matter of priority by this service relate to copyright piracy on a commercial scale by a
manufacturer, wholesaler or importer.
The Public Prosecution Service of Canada (PPSC) is responsible for prosecuting offences under more
than 50 federal statutes, including the Copyright Act, and for providing prosecution-related legal advice to
law enforcement agencies, such as the RCMP.
The Canada Border Services Agency (CBSA): The Combating Counterfeit Products Act provides the
following new powers to the CBSA: i) temporarily detain suspected counterfeit and pirated goods on their
initiative or at the request of rights holders, ii) contact rights holders regarding suspected counterfeit or
pirated shipments, and iii) provide rights-holders with information to facilitate a civil action.
Currently, the CBSA relies on the RCMP, or other government departments such as Health Canada,
when counterfeit or pirated products are identified through the course of regular duties at the border in
order for appropriate enforcement action to be undertaken. The CBSA will detain alleged counterfeit
content when presented with a court order to this effect.
Current debate
Summary of recent debates: The public debate on “copyrights in the age of the Internet” seems to be
relatively advanced in Canada. It has been taking place for several years, and gathered numerous experts
from the government, academia, think tanks, industry and civil society.
Each time an amendment to the copyright regime is planned, a public debate takes place. For
example, a study of the Copyright Act, entitled “Supporting Culture and Innovation”, was concluded in
2002 and tabled in Parliament, as required by the Copyright Act 182.
More recently, in 2009, the Canadian Government launched public consultations on copyright policy.
It provided a platform for several discussion themes that looked at various aspects of the planned reform,
such as: "Copyright and You", "Test of Time", "Innovation and Creativity", "Competition and Investment"
and "Digital Economy". For example, the theme "Copyright and You" looked for inputs on how Canada's
copyright laws affect individual consumers and how should existing laws be modernised. The theme
"Innovation and Creativity" asked discussants what sorts of copyright changes would best foster innovation
and creativity in Canada. The debates informed the Government of Canada’s modernisation of copyright
legislation 183.
In 2014, the government launched its Digital Canada 150 initiative, which represents a comprehensive
approach to taking full advantage of the opportunities of the digital age. The objective is that by 2017:
•
The majority of consumers will have access to high-speed Internet at 5 megabits per second
(Mbps) and to the latest wireless technologies;
•
Consumers will be protected from online threats and misuse of digital technology;
•
Canadians will have the skills and opportunities necessary to succeed in an interconnected global
economy;
•
The government of Canada will demonstrate leadership in the use of digital technologies and
open data; and
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
243 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
Copyright-intensive industries will have greater capabilities to seize digital opportunities,
promote Canadian content and play a more prominent role in the global marketplace.
Industry associations: There are many industry associations in Canada, including in the music, film
and television, books and periodicals, visual arts, videogames and broadcasting sectors. In light of the fact
that Canada is a bilingual country, there are often associations whose activities focus on the English
Canadian market and those whose activities focus on the French Canadian market 184. These associations
carry out a number of activities, including: i) lobbying, stakeholder coordination and engaging in public
debate about copyright, ii) collective rights management, iii) countering copyright infringement
(intelligence collection, collaboration with relevant enforcement authorities, training of public authorities),
iv) awareness raising campaigns in the area of copyrights, and v) data collection.
Industry best practices Major Canadian Internet Service Providers (ISP) have voluntarily
participated in a "notice and notice" regime for a number of years. Under this system, when an ISP receives
a notice from a copyright holder that a subscriber might be infringing copyright, it forwards a notice to the
subscriber. The identity of the subscriber may then be released with a court order. The Copyright
Modernization Act includes a provision that formalises this system.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
244 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Chile
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
Value added: The existing dataset present only a general picture of copyright-intensive industries in
Chile. According to the data presented by the Chilean National Council for Culture and the Arts on cultural
industries in general, copyright-intensive industries contributed 1.58% of the GDP in 2009.
Employment: Unfortunately, there is no detailed datasets on copyright-intensive industries in Chile.
The existing data published by the National Council for Culture and the Arts indicated that the copyrightintensive sector employed 2.3% of total employees in Chile.
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: In Chile the legal issue of copyrights is regulated by the
Law N°17336 Intellectual Property Act that first passed in 1970, and amended several times.
Recent evolution: The main recent amendment was made in 2010 with the focus to counter digital
piracy and protect the rights of content creators given the recent technological changes 185.
Duration of copyright: In Chile copyright protection generally ends 70 years following the death of
the last living author.
Institutional setting: Departamento de Derechos Intelectuales (DDI) is the government special
agency in charge of the Intellectual Property Record: Copyrights and Related Rights (Title IV Law N°
17.336 and its Regulations). Since its creation in 1970 the DDI depends on the Dirección de Bibliotecas,
Archivos y Museos (DIBAM) and has the specific mission of manage the public records related with
copyright and related rights, foster the protection of such rights and keep the fixations of the intellectual
productions that make its collections contributing thus with the formation, development and sustainability
de national culture of respect for the intellectual property.
The DDI has the following functions:
•
To register intellectual works.
•
To register acts and contracts of assignment or transfer of copyright and related and their
termination.
•
To register publishing contracts for literary works, judgments and pseudonyms.
•
To issue relevant certificates.
•
To examine queries and to issue reports for the privates and public services.
•
To provide advice to the government in all matters related with copyright and related rights.
In addition, to the DDI, two other institutions have copyright-related functions. The National Council
for the Culture and the Arts (CNCA) distributes grants to right holders and runs awareness campaigns.
DIRECON, is responsible for copyright issues related to the foreign policy. It coordinates with relevant
national agencies and participates and represents Chile in relevant international fora.
Database protection: There is no sui generis protection of databases in Chile. Databases that meet
the requirements for copyright protection are treated under copyright law like any other work.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
245 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Limitations and exceptions: Chile adopted recently a system that permits in certain cases legal,
unauthorised copying of copyrighted material. It includes for example creation of backup software copies
or citations. The relevant provisions were introduced by the law N° 20.435 that amended the Intellectual
Property Act in 2010. It includes the Title III called Limitaciones y Excepciones al Derecho de Autor y los
Derechos Conexos 186.
Orphan works: There is no explicit policy for orphan works in Chile.
Copyright registration: Registration is voluntary and in case of infringement greatly facilitates
potential judicial actions. The DDI holds the copyright register in Chile.
Enforcement: Chile’s IP enforcement agencies are the following:
Police of Investigations of Chile (Policia de Investigaciones de Chile, PDI) established in 2008 its
Brigada Investigadora de Delitos de Propiedad Intelectual (BRIDEPI), a dedicated unit to deal with
intellectual property crimes.
The National Council for Culture and the Arts (CNCA) and the Secretariat for the Prevention of
Crime have recently signed an agreement which, among other things, is going i) to facilitate the transfer of
information necessary to efficiently combat crimes against intellectual property ii) to establish a list of
crimes for which information is delivered quarterly.
Custom Authorities are in charge of the enforcement of the Title II Borders Measures for the
enforcement of Intellectual Property Right Law N° 19912.
Current debate
Industry associations and industry initiatives: There are several industry associations in Chile,
including industry groups in several sectors, and collective societies. The main ones include: International
Federation of the Phonographic Industry – Chile, Motion Picture Licensing Corporation Chile, and SCD
(Sociedad Chilena del Derecho de Autor). These associations carry out a number of activities, including:
i) lobbying, stakeholder coordination and engaging in public debate about copyright ii) collective rights
management, iii) countering copyright infringement (intelligence collection, collaboration with relevant
enforcement authorities, training of public authorities) and awareness raising campaigns in the area of
copyrights.
Several good examples of relevant industry initiative can be found in the area of education and
outreach, such as the alliance between CERLALC, UNESCO and DDI "united for the education of
children". This initiative provides essential educational tools for a child to learn about the importance of
copyright and related rights and their societal impacts 187. Another example that can be highlighted is the
campaign "Protect your idea" that promotes the rules related to the enforcement. This campaign was a joint
initiative of public and private institutions 188.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
246 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Egypt
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
The existing dataset present only a general picture of copyright-intensive industries in Egypt. In
particular, lack of detailed statistics at the industry level does not permit to estimate the precise
contribution of copyright-intensive industries to Egyptian GDP, and their share of employment using the
WIPO (2003) classification method. Available studies suggest that copyright-intensive industries
contributed to up to 0.5% of the Egyptian GDP in 2000 (WIPO, 2003 and Harabi, 2004) 189. Available
estimates provide also some picture of foreign trade of copyright-intensive sectors in Egypt with export
volumes of USD 898 million in 2008 and import volumes of USD 602 million imports 190. These statistics
can be explained in terms of existence of the copyright-intensive industries implicitly in these exports and
imports. Caution should be paid, when interpreting these results, since the presented data is rather old, and
since not all copyright-intensive industries were taken into account.
Some other available data present Egypt’s developed markets for creative content, where copyrightintensive thrive. An illustrative example is the Egyptian movie industry that dominates Arabic movie
production. Estimates suggest that the majority of all movies in Arabic are produced in Egypt (WIPO,
2003). It should be kept in mind that there are more than 422 million native speakers of Arabic according
to UNESCO, but it is hard to assess the precise number 191. Moreover, the cultural links between Arab
countries go far beyond the common language and meld into literature, cinema, music and other media that
are shared within the Arabic-speaking region. This is reflected in available data on the movie industry.
Between 2000 and 2013 this industry produced yearly 34 movies on average, with some fluctuations over
that period (Figure 5.17). Apart from exports to other countries, this production also supported domestic
theatre sector that reported constant growth over the recent years (Figure 5.18).
Figure 5.17.
Film production in Egypt, 2007 – 2012
Source: Based on information from the Egyptian Chamber of Cinema Industry
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
247 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.18.
New theatre registrations in Egypt, 2007 – 2012
Source: Based on information from the Egyptian Chamber of Cinema Industry
Finally, some relevant insights on copyright-related activities of Egyptian ICT industry can be found
in a survey based study of Egyptian SME’s in the ICT sector by Hegazy and Gadallah (2013). Their study
found that these enterprises are particularly active in terms of copyright licensing: 43% of the surveyed
SMEs grant licensing in copyright and neighbouring rights, whereas 39% of them use copyright and
neighbouring rights licenses granted by other firms (See Annex for more details).
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: In Egypt the legal issue of copyrights is regulated by the Law No. 82
(2002), Book 3 starting from the Article No. 138 to Article No. 188.
Duration of copyright: In Egypt copyright protection generally depends on the type of work. For
authors of copyrighted work, copyright ends 50 years after their death (50 years calculated from the
production or publishing date if the owner is not a person). For performers, copyrights end 50 years after
the performance. For broadcasts, copyrights ends 20 years after broadcasting year.
It should be highlighted that this durations does not apply to moral rights, which do not expire in
Egypt.
Institutional setting: In Egypt the Permanent Office for the Protection of Copyright at the Ministry
of Culture is primarily in charge of copyright-related issues. In addition, the Broadcasting and AudioVisual Work Protection Office at the Ministry of Information deals with audio-visual work, and the
intellectual Property Rights Protection office at the Information technology industry development Agency
(ITIDA) is in charge of software-specific issues.
Database protection: There is no sui generis protection of databases in Egypt. Databases that meet
the requirements for copyright protection are treated under copyright law like any other work.
Limitations and exceptions: According to the Egyptian law (Article No. 171) the following cases of
use for copyrighted material do not require copyright holder’s approval:
•
Use of work in family context or student gathering within the educational institution, to the
extent that no direct or indirect financial remuneration is required;
•
Making a single copy of the work for exclusive personal use, provided that such a copy shall
not hamper the normal exploitation of the work, nor cause undue prejudice to the legitimate
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
248 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
interests of the author or copyright holders. It should be highlighted that there are several
exceptions to this case, such as: i) reproduction or copying works of fine, applied or plastic
arts, unless they were displayed in a public place, or works of architecture; ii) reproduction or
copying of all or a substantial part of the notes of a musical work; iii) reproduction or copying
of all or a substantial part of a database or computer program.
•
Making a single copy or an adaptation of a computer program for archiving purposes or to
replace a lost, destroyed or invalid original copy (with rights holder’s consent).
•
Analysis of copyrighted work, excerpts, quotations, criticism, discussion or information.
•
Reproduction based on protected works for legal or administrative purposes, provided that the
source and the name of the author are mentioned.
•
Reproduction of short extracts from a work for teaching purposes in educational institutions.
•
A single copy of the work for documentation or archiving purposes in a dedicated archiving
centre.
•
Ephemeral reproduction of a work where such reproduction is made in relay, during a digital
transmission of the work or in the course of a process of reception of a digitally stored work,
within the normal operation of the device used by an authorised person.
Orphan works: There is no explicit policy for orphan works in Egypt.
Copyright registration: Copyright registration in Egypt is voluntary and in case of infringement
greatly facilitates potential judicial actions. Most works can be registered at the Copyright protection
office, Ministry of culture. In addition audio and video works can be registered with the Ministry of
Information, some software work can be registered with the Information technology industry development
Agency (ITIDA). Fees depend on the type of registered work, and vary between EGP 25 (USD 3.50) and
EGP 500 (USD 70). See the Annex 2 for more details.
Enforcement: The Investigation Unit within the Ministry of Interior is dedicated to copyright
infringement cases. In addition Egyptian Customs authorities are currently working on a mechanism for
improved handling of imports and exports of pirated products.
Current debate
Industry associations and industry initiatives: There are several industry associations in Egypt,
including industry groups in several sectors, and collective societies. These associations include:
• Egyptian Chamber of Cinema Industry (includes
1797 industrial institutions - companies)
• Society of Authors, Composers and Publishers
of the Arab Republic of Egypt
• Alam El Phan (media group)
• Egyptian Chamber of Printing Industry
• Egyptian Chamber of Information Technology &
Communication Industry
• El Massah
• Oscar for Production & Cinema Distribution
• El Nasr Film
• Arab Society
Distribution
for
Cinema
Production&
• El Sobki Film For Cinema Production
• Albatros Artistic Production &Distribution
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
249 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
• Egyptian Publisher Association (503 Member)
(EPA)
• Egyptian Writers Union (Writers' Union of
Egypt) (879 Member)
• The Egyptian Film Centre (CNC) (The National
Film center)
• El Sobki Video Film
• New Century Production
• Al Adl Group
• United Brothers Cinema Production
• Film Clinic
• Media Production City (MPC)
• Karim Sobki Films/ Production & distribution
• Rotana Group
• Good News for Film & Music
• Cinema professions Syndicate
• United Artistic Group
• Applied arts designers syndicates
• Misr Cinema & Artistic Production
• Syndicate of Actors
• GuirguisFawzi Films
• Syndicate of Musicians
• MISR Al-Alameya Films
• Syndicate of Artists
• Film House
•
Syndicate of Artistic applied professions
These associations carry out a number of activities, including:
•
Collective rights management; done by the Society of Authors, Composers and Publishers of
the Arab Republic of Egypt (SACERAU), a multi-disciplinary collective management body.
•
Countering copyright infringement (intelligence collection, collaboration with relevant
enforcement authorities, training of public authorities).
•
Awareness raising campaigns in the area of copyrights.
•
Data collection.
Concerning industry initiatives, an illustrative example is the Egyptian Publisher Association that has
recently completed drafting of the rules of good practices for the publishing profession. It also held a
number of training courses in co-operation with the German Goethe Institute. Currently new training
programs are being developed in co-operation with the chamber of printing industry.
Egypt country study annex 1: Copyright-related activities in the Egyptian ICT industry (SMEs)
In the context of Egyptian copyright-related industry, some lessons can be drawn from a empirical
study by Hegazy and Gadallah (2013), who surveyed micro, small and medium enterprises in the IICT
field. In terms of value added they found that 53.5% out of all the responding firms reported their outputs
to be used as inputs for other enterprises in the market, which reflect good backward and forward network
integration among enterprises. This can be explained in high value added and hence more of injection in
the GDP. In addition to 42.8% of the selected sample reported that the nature of their products is more a
service than goods. Furthermore, about 86.6% of the surveyed enterprises stated that the intellectual
property IPR of their products represents original efforts of these enterprises which reflect the importance
of IPR in this industry. However, only 24.6% of the selected sample legally protected their intellectual
assets.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
250 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
As noted in Figure 5.19, 43% of the surveyed enterprises grant licenses in copyright and neighbouring
rights, 15% in trade and service marks and 13% in petty patents. On the other hand, there is small number
of enterprises responded report any information about the percentage of royalty out of their annual net
profits they get it. Only 4 enterprises reported that they get less than one per cent as a royalty from
licensing their intellectual products to others versus 16 enterprises get less five per cent and six enterprises
ranged between three per cent and less than five per cent.
Figure 5.19.
Distribution of licensing by surveyed micro, small and medium enterprises
Source: Hegazy and Gadallah (2013).
Concerning the exploitation of the intellectual property of other enterprises by the surveyed
enterprises, about 26.2% of the sample reported that they produce based on a licensing from others. As
illustrated in Figure 5.20, 39% of the surveyed enterprises grant licensing in copyright and neighbouring
rights, 31% in trade and service marks, 10% in patents, 6% in petty patents and 5% in trade secrets.
Figure 5.20.
Distribution of licensing by other enterprises to the surveyed ones
Source: Hegazy and Gadallah (2013).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
251 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
To measure the return on R&D spending, Hegazy and Gadallah, (2013) surveyed the enterprises
asking about the type of their innovation as results of R&D spending. 64.7% of the sample reported that
they create new products while 10.7% of the sample told us that they succeeded in opening new markets
for their products versus 5.9% of the sample to create new process of production. Accordingly, it was
essential to ask them whether they depend on other enterprises to produce these innovations. Roughly
66.3% of the respondents in the sample clarified that their enterprises create the innovations totally rely on
themselves versus 14.9% partially by other enterprises. Moreover, 48.6% of the respondents decided that
their innovation had strong and positive influence on the performance of their enterprises, while the impact
was moderate as 26.2% of the sample reported.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
252 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Table 5.4.
Egypt country study annex 2: Copyright registration fees in Egypt
Copyright Protection Office, Ministry of Culture
A certificate for a written text of a work or design formation
EGP 200 (USD 28)
A certificate for the performance of an audio, or audio-visual work of one unit
or episode.
EGP200 (USD 28); fees
depend on the number of
episodes,
provided that they do not
exceed EGP 1,000 (USD 140)
A certificate for a recorded performance that does not exceed one hour
EGP 200 (USD 28)
A certificate for a recorded performance that does not exceed four hours.
EGP 500 (USD 70)
A certificate for an episode of a radio or TV broadcast.
EGP200 (USD 28); fees
depend on the number of
episodes,
provided that they do not
exceed EGP 1,000 (USD 140)
Broadcasting, Audio, and Audio-Visual Work Protection Office, Ministry of Information
Audio works
All kinds of speeches, symposiums and comments as well as political
analyses and religious material
EGP 200 (USD 28)
Poetry, lyrics, short stories, dramatic works and the elements thereof as well
as music and singing and the elements thereof
EGP300 (USD 42)
Audio-visual works
Celebrations, occasions, evening shows, documentary films, shows, cartoons
and graphics.
EGP400 (USD 56)
Tv series, sevenfold TV series, plays, as well as short and/or long movies
EGP 500 (USD 70)
The Intellectual Property Rights Protection Office, Information Technology Industry Development
Agency (ITIDA)
Educational computer works (software and databases) used in all kinds and
levels of education.
EGP25 (USD 3.50)
Computer works (software and databases) not related to education.
EGP 50 (USD 7)
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
253 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
The European Union
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
In 2010 the total contribution calculated for the core copyright-based industries 192 in the EU was 4.2%
of total GDP. The total number of people employed (full time) in copyright-intensive industries
represented 3.2% of all employees (Figure 5.21). The numbers varied across the EU member states. The
highest contribution to the GDP was recorded for Ireland (8.1%), whereas the lowest for Portugal (3%),
Employment rates ranged between 2.3% (Poland and Portugal) and Sweden (5.3%).
Figure 5.21.
Added value and employment in copyright-intensive industries (2010, % of total)
9.0%
8.0%
7.0%
6.0%
5.0%
4.0%
3.0%
2.0%
1.0%
0.0%
% GDP
% Employment
Source: EPO-OHIM (2013).
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: The copyright law of the EU consists of a number of directives and
aims to harmonise the differing copyright laws of the EU member states. The member states are obliged to
include these directives into their national legal frameworks. Specifically, the relevant ones are the
Directives of the European Parliament and of the Council on:
•
collective management of copyright and related rights and multi-territorial licensing of rights in
musical works for online use in the internal market (2014/26/EU)
•
certain permitted uses of orphan works (2012/28/EU)
•
the legal protection of computer programs (2009/24/EC)
•
rental right and lending right and on certain rights related to copyright in the field of intellectual
property (2006/115/EC)
•
the term of protection of copyright and certain related rights (2006/116/EC and 2011/77/EU)
•
enforcement of intellectual property rights (Enforcement Directive, 2004/48/EC)
•
on the resale right for the benefit of the author of an original work of art (2001/84/EC)
•
on the harmonisation of certain aspects of copyright and related rights in the information society
(Copyright Directive, 2001/29/EC)
•
the legal protection of databases (96/9/EC).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
254 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
Council Directive 93/83/EEC of 27 September 1993 on the coordination of certain rules
concerning copyright and rights related to copyright applicable to satellite broadcasting and cable
retransmission (93/83/EEC)
Duration of copyright: Directive 2006/115/EC harmonised the term of protection of copyright
setting it 70 years following the death of the last living author and neighbouring rights (50 years from the
moment triggering the protection, e.g. the fixation of a phonogram). Directive 2011/77/EU extended the
term of protection for performers and the producers of sound recordings to 70 years.
Database protection: The 1996 introduced Database Directive (96/9/EC) aims to provide harmonised
copyright protection to databases in the EU. It introduces a new specific sui generis right for the creators of
databases. According to this Directive databases that do not qualify for copyright protection, enjoy a 15year protection.
Limitations and exceptions: The Copyright Directive outlines an exhaustive list of optional specific
copyright exceptions which EU member states may introduce into national legislation. It includes, for
example copies made for teaching or scientific research purposes, quotations for purposes such as criticism
or review, caricature, parody or pastiche, etc 193.
Orphan works: Generally, the issue of orphan works has not been regulated so far the EU level. The
Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on certain permitted uses of orphan works
(2012/28/EU) sets out common rules on the digitisation and dissemination of orphan works. The Directive
will be implemented in the legislation of the Member States by the 29th October 2014.
Copyright registration: Copyright cannot be registered at the EU level. However, the EU copyright
framework does not regulate the possibility to introduce voluntary registration of copyright works.
Enforcement: Article 8 of the 2001/29/EC Directive (InfoSoc Directive) 194 introduces provision that
EC member states shall introduce in the area of on-line copyright enforcement. It calls for appropriate
sanctions and remedies in respect of infringements of copyrights, effective enforcement, and enabling
rights’ holders to apply for an injunction against intermediaries whose services are used by a third party to
infringe a copyright or related right.
The Directive on the enforcement of intellectual property rights (2004/48/EC) refers to all intellectual
property rights including copyright and related rights. This Directive creates a level playing field for right
holders in the EU by requiring all Member States to apply effective, dissuasive and proportionate remedies
and penalties against those engaged in counterfeiting and piracy.
Current debate
Summary of recent debates: With the emphasis on completing the Digital Single Market to help
deliver growth in Europe, the debate on copyright has intensified in Europe over the last few years, and
gathered numerous experts from the member states’ governments, industry (see below) and civil society
(e.g. European Digital Rights, EDRI; The European Consumers' Organisation, BEUC).
The “Green Paper on copyright in the knowledge economy” provided a starting point for the debate 195
and triggered the copyright-related discussion in the EU.
This was in turn reflected in in several subsequent actions, such as the initiative Licences for Europe
launched by the Commission in 2013. The initiative was launched in February 2013 with the objective to
deliver industry-led solutions to address practical barriers to the circulation of content in the digital age. It
involved active participation of numerous stakeholders, mostly from the copyright-intensive industries. At
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
255 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
its closing session in November 2013, Licences for Europe participants made several pledges to overcome
problems European citizens may face in four areas: cross-border access and portability of services; usergenerated content and micro-licensing; audio-visual heritage and text and data mining.
Shortly after the Licences for Europe closing session, the EC launched official public consultations on
the review of the EU copyright rules. The consultations have generated broad interest with more than 9500
replies received from a wide range of stakeholders including users, consumers, right holders, industry,
collective management organisations and governments 196.
In addition, recently, numerous EU member countries have called for views for the debate, and
several member states conduct debates on that topic.
Industry associations: There are many industry associations in The EU, including in the music, film
and television, books and periodicals, visual arts, videogames and broadcasting sectors. The main ones
include:
•
Business Software Alliance (BSA)
•
European Federation of Journalists (EFJ)
•
European Grouping of Societies of Authors and Composers (GESAC)
•
Federation Internationale des Acteurs (FIA)
•
Federation of European Publishers (FEP - FEE)
•
Interactive Software Federation of Europe (ISFE)
•
International Federation of the Phonographic Industry (IFPI)
•
International Video Federation (IVF)
•
Sports Rights Owners Coalition (SROC)
•
The European Newspaper Publishers' Association (ENPA)
•
The Society of Audiovisual Authors (SAA)
•
UNI Global Union media, entertainment & arts (UNI MEI)
•
European Federation of Joint Management Societies of Producers for Private Audiovisual
Copying (EUROCOPYA)
•
Independent Music Companies Association (IMPALA)
These associations carry out a number of activities, including: i) lobbying, stakeholder coordination
and engaging in public debate about copyright ii) collective rights management, iii) countering copyright
infringement (intelligence collection, collaboration with relevant enforcement authorities, training of
public authorities), iv) awareness raising campaigns in the area of copyrights, and v) data collection.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
256 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Italy
State of the Internet
In recent years access to broadband networks and the Internet has steadily increased in Italy. In
addition, further deployments of fibre networks have taken place. Overall, however, broadband penetration
rates and the deployment of fibre in Italy are still below the OECD averages (see Figure 5.22).
Figure 5.22.
Broadband penetration rates in Italy
2002-2013, per 100 inhabitants
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD)
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Italy)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Italy)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
More recently there has been rapid and substantial growth in mobile broadband access in Italy,
opening up new communication possibilities to people as they are away from a fixed-line connection.
Mobile broadband penetration has grown to 65% in Italy, which is at a comparable level with the OECD
average that has grown to more than 70% (Figure 5.23).
Figure 5.23.
Mobile broadband subscriptions in Italy
2009-2013, per 100 inhabitants
80.00
70.00
60.00
50.00
40.00
30.00
20.00
10.00
0.00
2009-Q4 2010-Q2 2010-Q4 2011-Q2 2011-Q4 2012-Q2 2012-Q4 2013-Q2 2013-Q4
Italy
OECD
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
257 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
Value added: Over the past years copyright-intensive industries in Italy have demonstrated overall
stable performance 197. Between 2008 and 2011 the total share of the copyright-based industries within the
Italian economy remained rather stable, accounting for 3.65% of Italy’s GDP in 2011 (Figure 5.24).
Figure 5.24.
Added value of copyright-Intensive industries in Italy
2008-2011, % of GDP
4.2%
4.0%
3.8%
3.6%
3.4%
3.2%
3.0%
2008
2009
2010
2011
% of GDP
Source: Eurostat SBS database and EPO-OHIM (2013).
Employment: In 2011 the total number of people employed in copyright-intensive industries
represented 2.3% of all employed by Italian industry. Between 2008 and 2011, the overall share of people
employed in copyright-intensive industries in total industry employees remained relatively stable, reporting
some small fluctuations. The total employment also reported some fluctuations over that period. In 2011 it
amounted to 641,000, which was slightly less than the volume of employment in these industries in 2008
(Figure 5.25).
Figure 5.25.
Employment in copyright-intensive industries
% of total employment (left axis) and volume of employment (right axis)
2.60%
680,000
2.55%
670,000
2.50%
660,000
2.45%
2.40%
650,000
2.35%
640,000
2.30%
630,000
2.25%
2.20%
2008
2009
% of total employment
2010
2011
620,000
Number of employees
Source: Eurostat SBS database.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
258 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Copyright-intensive industries and the Internet economy: Italian copyright-intensive industries
successfully leverage the technical opportunities offered by the Internet. Several of successful start-ups can
be found in the music, gaming and video sectors (see Box). In addition Italian fashion industry also takes
advantage of the copyrights in order to protect content and creations in addition to other, more
conventional ways of IPR protection, such as design and trademarks (see Box 5.5.).
Box 5.5. Italian creative businesses on the Internet: Dropin, Chili-TV, Jaqard
Dropin is a "cloud recording studio" that can be accessed from a desktop or from a mobile device. Users of Dropin
can create their own music, based on dedicated software and share it with other users. Users of Dropin include A
artists, bands, and music professionals.
Chili-TV is, one of the most rapidly growing Italian legitimate platforms for movie streaming and downloads. Over
the past few it has reached volume of content comparable to the biggest international competitors. Chili-TV builds
its strategy on several pillars, including user-friendly design and quick service delivery, competitive pricing
schemes and cooperation with main Italian national multimedia groups (RCS) and main players in other content
distribution channels (e.g. UCI Cinemas).
Jaquard is an on-line personal styling community that brings together fashion and software industries. Based on
a dedicated mobile app Jaquard facilitates information and advice exchange in the area of personal style and
fashion. Questions that Jaquard community addresses are: "What could I wear with this?", "What looks similar
with this?" and "What else is in this style?"
The term “lyrics” is one of top searched term on Google, which indicates that a large number of users people
every month Google “lyrics” in order to get song’s lyrics for their music but since musiXmatch launched on the
market it has changed consumer behaviors by allowing users to scan their music library to retrieve lyrics via
musiXmatch apps. musiXmatch’s idea in early 2010 was to build the world’s largest lyrics catalog and have it
licensed with Top Music Publishers like Sony/ATV,Warner Chappell, Universal Music Publishing Group, EMI
Publishing, BMGChrysalis, Kobalt Publishing, and Harry Fox Agency for worldwide distribution. Currently
musiXmatch is the most popular lyrics destination on mobile and connected devices with more than 20 million
people in the world. musiXmatch provides also an Official Lyrics API (application program interface), empowering
3rd party companies and apps with musiXmatch’s lyrics catalog to the music market.
Sources: https://www.dropin.fm, http://www.chili-tv.it/, http://www.jaqard.com, http://musixmatch.com/resources/
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: In Italy the legal issue of copyrights is regulated by the Diritto
d'autore (Copyright law) no. 633 of 22 April 1941. Over the years, the law of copyright has been updated
through several national amendments and the transposition of European directives.
Recent evolution: Over the past years there have been several amendments of the Copyright Act. The
main recent ones include:
•
1993: Introduction of private permitted use (see the point “Limitations and exceptions).
•
2004: Prohibition of peer-to-peer exchange of protected files regardless of the intended use of the
shared file. The “Urbani Decree” dating back to 2004 established that even those making use of
protected files for purely personal purposes may be liable to punishment; before the decree came
into effect, there were no penalties for sharing files protected by copyright where the use was not
for profit. The Urbani Decree was converted into Law 128 on 18 May 2004, with the introduction
of alternative penalties (fines instead of prison as in the first draft of the decree) for the users
caught in the act of breaching the copyright law.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
259 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
2009: The Italian legislative decree of 8 June 2001 number 231 introduced criminal liability for
companies, linked to the commission of certain crimes, made by managers or employees, which
provides for pecuniary penalties and disqualification. Companies would survive their liability
claims if they can prove that they have adopted and updated a specific document named
“organisational model” aimed at the prevention of certain crimes. Law number 99 of 2009
extended the list of such crimes to certain offenses set forth in the Italian copyright law.
•
2013: By Law n. 112 of October 7, 2013 (published in G.U. of 8 October 2013, n. 236), the Article
15 of the Copyright Law was modified by adding the following last paragraph: “The public
recitation of literary works effected, without purpose of gain, within public museums, libraries and
archives, for the exclusive purpose of cultural promotion and valorisation of the same works, to
identified on the ground of memorandums of understanding between SIAE and the Ministry of
Culture is not to be considered as a public performance.”
•
2014: After a long parliamentary discussion, the Chambers approved a bill (Law 67/2014)
decriminalising various offenses under the Italian law (it converts various offences into civil
wrongs). Article 2 of the law excludes the IPR matters from the decriminalisation process.
•
2014: The Decree of June 20, 2014 by the Ministry for Heritage and Cultural Activities (MiBAC)
(Official Gazette n.155 del 7-7-2014) has updated the amounts of private copying levies on
recordable media and on apparatus provided with electronic memory.
Duration of copyright: In Italy copyright protection generally ends 70 years following the death of
the last living author. In cases when rights are held by academia, non-profit organisation, or public
institutions copyright protection ends 20 years from the first public presentation.
Institutional setting: In Italy the issues related to copyright are within the competencies of:
•
•
The Ministry for Heritage and Cultural Activities and Tourism (MiBACT) at the Third Service
Copyright and Supervision of the “Società Italiana degli Autori e Editori”(SIAE) of the
Directorate General for libraries, cultural institution and copyright.
The Presidency of the Council of Ministers at the Department for Information and Publishing
In addition, the Guardia di Finanza (Fiscal Police) is the main enforcement authority for most of the
copyright sectors. The Fiscal Police deals with cases involving infringement of film, music, software and
videogames, in cooperation with the “GAT” department, a special division dedicated to online fraud.
Database protection: In Italy if a database meets the originality criteria, it is treated as a literary
work and is protected under the law of copyright. In addition, all databases in the Italy are protected by Act
of 27 July 2001 on databases protection, which followed the directive 96/9/EC of the European Parliament
and of the Council, of 11 March 1996 on the legal protection of databases.
Limitations and exceptions: Italian law allows for reproduction use of copyrighted material for
private purposes. In addition existing regulations permit the use of copyrighted material for the purpose of
criticism, parody, public debate and non-commercial teaching.
Orphan works: This area does not seem to be yet explicitly regulated by the Italian national
legislation. Projects of new legislation that will comply with the directive of the European Parliament and
of the Council on certain permitted uses of orphan works (2012/28/EU) are currently debated.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
260 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Copyright registration: Copyright can be registered in Italy before the Public Registry of Protected
Works, held by the Ministry for Heritage and Cultural Activities (MiBAC), with the exception of movies
and audio-visual work (for which a special registry provided for by law 1001/2010 is not operative as of
yet) and with the exception of software. Software can be registered in the “Registro Pubblico Speciale per
Programmi per Elaboratore”, held by SIAE ("Società Italiana degli Autori ed Editori”)
Enforcement: Concerning enforcement, most actions in this area are co-ordinated by the Fiscal
Police (Guardia di Finanza) in co-operation with a special police department dedicated to online fraud
(GAT). In 2013 GAT carried out some of the most effective and large-scale operations against online
copyright infringements, with actions against some of most significant international illegal portals
available in Italy, as well as investigations and seizures of some well-known Italian sites. Other successful
actions taken by the Fiscal Police include actions against Italian linking sites, illegal streaming services
with movies and television program and cyberlockers sites.
Regarding the enforcement-related legislation, the new regulation that came into force March 2014
enables Italian Communications Regulatory Authority (AGCOM) to order, after verifying the violation, the
removal of content protected by copyright uploaded illegally on website hosted in Italy and to block access
to website hosting massive piracy including those outside Italian jurisdiction 198. On Sept. 26, 2014, the
Administrative Court of Lazio referred to the Italian Constitutional Court a question regarding the
constitutionality of AGCOM regulation in particular to check if blocking orders issued by an
administrative body, such as AGCOM, comply with constitutional principles, including freedom of
expression, economic freedom and proportionality.
Current debate
Summary of recent debates: The debate on the copyright in the age of the Internet seems to be
relatively advanced in Italy. The main participants in the debate are the Italian government (Ministry for
Heritage and Cultural Activities and Tourism, and the Presidency of the Council of Ministers), the
regulator, AGCOM, the industry associations (see below) and consumers associations.
The two main topics that are currently debated are: the application of the rules of the new regulation
issued by Italian Communications Regulatory Authority that came into force on March 2014, and the
debate on potential reform of copyright at the EU level.
Industry associations: In Italy, there are several associations, industry chambers and collective
management organisations of copyright-intensive industries in Italy. The main association is the public
organisation "Società Italiana degli Autori ed Editori” (SIAE). In addition some of these associations are
gathered in the associations of copyright-intensive industries, “Confindustria Cultura Italia” 199. They
include:
•
IMAE (Performing Artists)
•
Confindustria Radio Televisioni; CRTV (radio and TV broadcasting)
•
Motion Picture Licensing Corporation Italy
•
SCF Consorzio Fonografici (phonographic industry)
•
Diritti Artisti IPAA (music and audio-visual industry)
•
AGIS (Italian Show Business Association)
•
ANICA (Italian Film Producer’s Association);
•
FAPAV (Audio-visual and Multimedia Content Protection Federation);
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
261 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
UNIVIDEO (Italian Union of Audio-visual Publishers);
These associations carry out a number of activities, including: i) collective rights management ii)
countering copyright infringement (intelligence collection, collaboration with relevant enforcement
authorities, and training of public authorities) iii) awareness raising campaigns in the area of copyrights,
and iv) data collection.
Examples of best practices: In 2004, the Italian government promoted the so-called “Charter of
Sanremo”- a code of conduct shared by the government and stakeholders to foster the availability of
quality content and ensure the respect of digital rights - and to the revision of the “Urbani Decree” on
downloading copyright music from peer-to-peer networks. In addition in June 2014, a, a self-regulatory
initiative of IAB Italy, FPM and FAPAV was presented with the aim to combat piracy on the internet
through blocking ads on illegal platforms.
Italy country study annex: Italian Broadcasting Industry in the Age of the Internet 200
This annex presents television-related on-line content in Italy 201.
RAI.TV is the public broadcaster multimedia portal offering 15 TV channels and 10 radio channels in
live streaming over Interne; 7 RAI Replay channels (streaming of last 7 day broadcast), on top of several
thematic areas and programme sites with audio and video podcast of selected current and archive episodes.
All content is available for free.
LA7.TV is the web portal of the Italian commercial TV channel La 7 offering for free streaming of all
contents broadcast in the last 2 weeks (full episodes, in full screen and HD). Service is available free to
PCs, interactive set top boxes and smart TVs.
MTV On Demand is the broadcaster’s streaming service offering programs broadcast on MTV
channels. The free service also provides Internet exclusive content.
SKY On Demand is the video-on-demand service available to Sky’s subscribers equipped with My
Sky HD set top box. Contents are available for one week after broadcast and include film, entertainment
programs, TV series, documentaries, sport magazines and events, children’s programmes, events and
concerts.
SKY GO is an app offering over 30 channels of Sky’s platform in streaming on second screens and
mobile devices (pc, tablet, smartphone). Service allows access to Sky On Demand library of film, TV
series, entertainment, documentaries, etc.
SKY Online is a subscription service open to everyone and offering in streaming to internet
connected device a selection of Sky’s offer. Sky online, by using Internet as the main mean to access
content, targets mainly digital native public.
VideoMediaset.IT, allows web users to watch entire episodes of Mediaset’s programmes, including
the complete version of every newscast. The other programmes offered over the video portal, besides the
entertainment programmes, include soap operas, current affairs and sports programmes, which can all be
watched in high-quality full-screen mode. VideoMediaset content is also available on the main social
networks along with snack-TV content.
Mediaset Rewind, On the main TV screen VideoMediaset is available as the catch-up TV service of
the last 7 days, accessible through smartTV sets via internet broadband connection.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
262 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Infinity, is an OTT service with a library of 5000 titles - on demand, in HD and original version, with
no commercial breaks – caters to multiple reception devices: pc, smartphone, smart TV, tablets and games
consoles, including Playstation 3 and the X-box. Infinity is available to all users in fast developing market
for the legal offer of OTT content.
Premium Play provides non–linear distribution across different platforms (personal computers,
connected TV sets, HD decoders and X-box consoles, Ipad) and features over 2000 programmes (including
news, sport, film, drama and entertainment). Every week, 200 new programmes are added afresh. The
premium “Download & Play" service enables subscribers to download, save on the device memory and
watch Mediaset’s on demand content without any internet connection, no additional charges and thus no
territorial restrictions.
16mm.it collects and shares videos in a way similar to many other platforms on the web. Users can
directly send their videos or respond to contests and calls to action on specific issues. To upload a video,
users are asked to abide by 10 rules in the terms of reference. All videos are pre-vetted before going public.
At present, 16 mm counts over 10.000 truly UGC videos, roughly 50 daily.
TIMvision is a multimedia video service accessible via Telecom Italia set top box or via ADSL and
mobile connected devices (PC, smart TV, smartphone). TIMvision library contains thousands of film titles,
sport events accessible on demand or via a dedicated App.
Additional AV offer not related to TV providers legally available over the Net in Italy include (NB:
comprehensive not exhaustive list):
•
ANICAONDEMAND: film, TV series and TV programs, documentaries, current and archive
content;
•
POPCORNTV: TV On-Demand service available on Pc/Mac, Apple and Android connected
device, connected TV;
•
SAMSUNG HUB: music, film, TV, games, eBooks, educational content especially optimised for
Samsung devices;
•
SONY ENTERTAINMENT NETWORK: allows access to high quality content via connected
TVs, videogame consoles and BluRay readers;
•
X-BOX LIVE: is the entertainment platform dedicated to Microsoft X-Box and allowing rental or
buy of HD film and TV programs;
•
APPLE ITUNES STORE: films on demand are accessible via the different iOs devices (iPhone,
’iPad, PC, Apple TV);
•
GOOGLE PLAY STORE: mainly films, accessible via several connected devices (PCs,
smartphones, tablets based on Android software), or over TV screens via Chromecast USB.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
263 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Japan
State of the Internet
In recent years access to broadband networks and the Internet has constantly increased in Japan.
In terms of fixed broadband, penetration levels have been growing constantly and are well above the
OECD average, reaching maturity. In addition, further deployments of fibre networks have taken place.
Overall, deployment of fibre in Japan is at a very advanced stage and places Japan among top countries in
the world (see Figure 5.26).
Figure 5.26.
Broadband penetration rates in Japan
2002-2013, per 100 inhabitants
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2002
2003
2004
2006
2005
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Japan)
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Japan)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
Mobile broadband access is opening up new communication possibilities to people as they are away
from a fixed-line connection. In 2013 mobile broadband penetration in Japan has grown to 111.79%,
meaning that some users have more than one subscription. This is well above the OECD average that has
grown to 72.37% (see Figure 5.27).
Figure 5.27.
Mobile broadband penetration rates in Japan
2009 Q4 – 2013 Q4, per 100 inhabitants
120
Japan made a change in the methodology of the data collection from 2013-Q2. This means that its
position is not comparable with previous data for the wireless broadband subscriptions.
100
80
60
40
20
0
2009-Q4
2010-Q2
2010-Q4
2011-Q2
2011-Q4
Japan
2012-Q2
2012-Q4
2013-Q2
2013-Q4
OECD
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
264 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
Value added: Over the past years copyright-intensive industries in Japan have demonstrated
generally good performance 202. In 2007 the total contribution calculated for the core copyright-based
industries was JPY 17 trillion, accounting for 3.2% of Japan’s GDP (Figure 5.28).
Figuere 5.28. Added value of copyright-Intensive industries in Japan
2002-2012, JPY billion (right axis) and % of GDP (left axis)
6.0%
25,000
5.0%
20,000
4.0%
15,000
3.0%
2.0%
10,000
1.0%
0.0%
5,000
1998
% of GDP, left axis
2007
Value added (JPY bn), right axis
Source: Japan Copyright Institute, 2009
Employment: Between 1998 and 2007, the overall share of people employed in copyright-intensive
industries in total industry employees reported an increase of 0.04 percentage point. In 2007 copyrightintensive industries in Japan employed 1.9 million people, which represented 3% of all employed (Figure
5.29).
Figure 5.29.
Employment in copyright-intensive industries
volume of employment (left axis) and % of industry employment (right axis)
4.0%
2,000
1,950
1,900
1,850
1,800
1,750
1,700
1,650
1,600
3.5%
3.0%
2.5%
2.0%
1.5%
1.0%
1998
2007
% of total employment, left axis
volume of employment (1000), right axis
Source: Japan Copyright Institute, 2009
Copyright-intensive industries and the Internet economy: Japanese industries, including
copyright-intensive industries, successfully leverage the technical opportunities offered by the Internet.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
265 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
The percentage of firms selling online has been rising in Japan for the past years, and the existing forecast
suggest that Japan will remain one of the most important e-commerce markets in terms of sales volumes 203.
A unique feature of Japan, compared to other OECD countries, is a very intense usage of mobile
broadband. For example, the number of daily mobile users who accessing news and information from their
mobile devices in Japan reached 57.6% in 2010, far more than in Europe and in the US 204. This trend also
affects copyright-intensive industries and was paralleled by emergence of numerous start-ups and business
models took the advantage of the mobile Internet as the distribution channel. Examples include the
emergence of a “cell-phone novel” (books) and a company NAMCO (games) (See Box 6).
Box 5.6. Japanese creative businesses on the Internet: cell-phone novels and Namco
A cell-phone novel is a literary work that is originally written on a mobile phone via text messaging. The content is sent
directly, chapter by chapter, to users through paid SMS text messages, or through dedicated online subscription site.
The Japanese publishing industry has quickly adopted cell-phone books into their product portfolio by offering them on
their sites, popularising information about them and by offering prizes to authors of good quality cell-phone novels.
NAMCO is a Japanese corporation that is best known as a former developer of video games for mobile phones.
Such games, mostly arcade-style, became large popularity in Japan in the early 2000s. NAMCO was very active on
that market, introducing several innovative solutions, such as use of mobile phone camera to personalise characters
that appear in games. In 2005 NAMCO merged with Bandai and continued to operate as Namco Bandai Games.
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: In Japan the legal issue of copyrights is regulated by the
Copyright Act (No. 48) that was first passed in 1970 and amended several times.
Recent evolution: Copyright law in the Japan have been amended several times in order to meet the
technological development, cope with changes in socio-economic landscape and to comply with the
evolving international landscape 205. The most recent amendment was made in 2012 (act No.43).
This amendment introduced some additional provisions related to the so-called incidental use of
copyrighted material. It also strengthened protection of copyright and related rights in order to increase the
efficiency of countering piracy.
Duration of copyright: For cinematographic works, copyright protection generally ends 70 years
following the publishing of the work, or 70 years since its creation (if it has not been made public within
70 years following its creation).
For other works, such as sound recordings, performances, books, etc. copyright protection generally
ends 50 years following the death of its author, or 50 years since its first publication (if the author is
unknown or if the copyright does not belong to an individual person).
Institutional setting: in Japan, the agency in charge of copyright issues is the Agency for Cultural
Affairs which belongs to the Japanese Ministry of Education, Sports, Science and Technology (MEXT).
Within the Agency most copyright-related tasks are assigned to its dedicated administrative unit, the
Japanese Copyright Office (JCO).
Database protection: Original databases that “by reason of the selection or systematic construction
of information contained therein, constitute intellectual creations” are protected by copyrights (Article 122). There is no legislation solely dedicated to copyright protection (sui generis) in Japan.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
266 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Limitations and exceptions: Japanese copyright law sets out a detailed set of cases when a
copyrighted work can be used without rights holder authorisation. These include (for example):
reproduction for private use, reproduction in libraries, quotations, reproduction in school textbooks,
broadcasting and wire diffusion in school education programs, reproduction and public transmission for
teaching materials at education institutions, etc 206. For each case, Japanese legislation provides a detailed
set of conditions to clearly define clearly the circumstances for legal, unauthorised use.
Orphan works: For use of orphan works, an application for a compulsory licence can be made to the
Agency for Cultural Affairs (ACA). It is possible to issue a compulsory licence for works of a foreign
author as long as the work will continue to be exploited within Japan.
Copyright registration: Copyright registration in Japan is voluntary, and can be done at the Agency
for Cultural Affairs. It establishes presumption of facts contained in registration for use in court, in cases of
copyright infringement or disputes.
Enforcement: Copyright infringement in Japan is generally a civil law matter and the prosecution
takes place only upon the legal complaint of the right owner. In addition to a set of civil remedies, the
Japanese legislation provides a list of penal sanction for copyright infringement, including
imprisonment 207.
Current debate
Recent debates: The public debate on “copyrights in the age of the Internet” seems to be relatively
advanced in Japan. An important forum for such debate is the Cultural Council Copyright Subcommittee 208
that works within the Agency for Cultural Affairs. The Subcommittee’s members come from the industry,
academia, and legal sector. The discussions take place in different thematic working teams, and touch upon
such specific subjects as content digitisation, types of contracts or remedies and litigation 209.
Whereas the debates that take place at the Subcommittee are rather specific and focus on detailed
topics, the “Copyright White Paper” (Japan Copyright Institute, 2009) published by the Japanese Copyright
Research and Information Center presents a general picture of Japanese copyright-intensive industries. It
analyses the annual trends of various macroeconomic indices that describe the industry, which in turn
positions the copyright industry in the national economy 210.
Industry associations: There are many industry associations in Japan, including in the music, film
and television, books and periodicals, visual arts, videogames and broadcasting sectors. The main ones
include 211: i) Japanese Society for Rights of Authors, Composers and Publishers (JASRAC), ii) Japan
Reproduction Rights Center (JRRC), iii) The Japan Writers' Association, iv) The Japan Art, Photograph
and Graphic Design Copyright Organisation (APG-Japan), v) Society for the Administration of
Remuneration for Video Home Recording (SARVH), vi) Society for the Administration of Remuneration
for Audio Home Recording, vii) Japan Council of Performers' Organisations (GEIDANKYO), and viii)
Recording Industry Association of Japan (RIAJ).
These associations carry out a number of activities, including: i) collective rights management,
ii) countering copyright infringement (intelligence collection, collaboration with relevant enforcement
authorities, training of public authorities), iii) awareness raising campaigns in the area of copyrights, and
iv) data collection.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
267 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Korea
State of the Internet
In recent years access to broadband networks and the Internet has constantly increased in Korea.
In terms of fixed broadband, penetration levels have been growing constantly and are well above the
OECD average, reaching maturity. In addition, further deployments of fibre networks have taken place.
Overall, deployment of fibre in Korea is at a very advanced stage and is well above the OECD average (see
Figure 5.30).
Figure 5.30.
Broadband penetration rates in Korea
2002-2013, per 100 inhabitants
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD average)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD average)
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Korea)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Korea)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
More recently there has been rapid and substantial growth in mobile broadband access in Korea,
opening up new communication possibilities to people as they are away from a fixed-line connection.
Mobile broadband penetration has grown to more than 100 subscriptions per 100 inhabitants in Korea,
meaning that some people have more than one subscription. This is way above the OECD average that has
grown to 72% (Figure 5.31).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
268 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.31.
Mobile broadband subscriptions in Korea
2009-2013, per 100 inhabitants
100
80
60
40
20
0
2009-Q4
2010-Q2
2010-Q4
2011-Q2
2011-Q4
Korea
2012-Q2
2012-Q4
2013-Q2
2013-Q4
OECD
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
Value added: Over the past years copyright-intensive industries in Korea have demonstrated overall
better performance than the overall economy of Korea, reporting between 2009 and 2011 average annual
growth rates of 13.0% 212.In addition, one should keep in mind that in 2010 there was an economic rebound,
after the 2008-2009 global financial crisis downturn. In absolute terms Korean copyright-intensive
industries contributed in 2011 KRW 47 246 billion to the Korean GDP (Figure 5.32) accounting for 4.37%
of Korea’s GDP.
Figure 5.32.
Added value of copyright-Intensive industries in Korea
2002-2012, KRW billion (right axis) and % of GDP (left axis)
6.00%
80,000
70,000
5.00%
60,000
4.00%
50,000
40,000
3.00%
30,000
2.00%
20,000
1.00%
10,000
0.00%
0
2009
2010
Value Added (right axis)
2011
% of GDP (left axis)
Source: Korea Copyright Commission (2013), The economic contribution of copyright industries in the Republic of Korea
Employment: Between 2009 and 2011, the overall share of people employed in copyright-intensive
industries in total industry employees reported a moderate increase. In 2011 the total number of people
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
269 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
employed in copyright-intensive industries represented 3.1% of all employed by Korean industry and
amounted to 762 000 employees (Figure 5.33) 213.
Figure 5.33.
Employment in copyright-intensive industries
volume of employment (thousands, right axis) and % of industry employment (left axis)
3.20%
780
3.15%
760
3.10%
740
3.05%
3.00%
720
2.95%
700
2.90%
680
2.85%
660
2.80%
640
2.75%
2.70%
620
2009
2010
Total employment (right axis)
2011
% of total (left axis)
Source: Korea Copyright Commission (2013), The economic contribution of copyright industries in the Republic of Korea
Copyright-intensive industries and the Internet economy: Korean copyright-intensive industries
successfully leverage the technical opportunities offered by the Internet. Among many start-ups in
copyright-intensive industries in Korea, some have performed remarkably well in taking advantage of the
Internet. Examples include Ocon Animation Studio and Iconix Entertainment (media), NCSOFT
Corporation (entertainment software) and YG Entertainment (music) (See Box 5.7.).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
270 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Box 5.7. Korean creative businesses on the Internet: Iconix, Ocon, NCSOFT, YG.
"Pororo the Little Penguin" (simply known as “Pororo”) is a cartoon series televised on EBS, Korean educational
broadcasting company. The program has been aired in more than 130 countries and the revenue in 2009
including license fees was estimated over KRW 258 billion. The cartoon series and their characters were created
jointly by Iconix Entertainment, Ocon and some other companies. Iconix Entertainment (established in 2001)
and Ocon (established in 1996) have produced animations and characters for children and tried to create new
markets through character merchandising and other means of secondary uses.
Both Iconix and Ocon have been grown very rapidly over the past years. In 2011 Iconix recorded KRW 34.3 billion
sales, an increase by 102.8% from 2009; nearly 70% of the sales were generated by Pororo. Ocon’s sales in
2009-2011 grew by 147.2% to KRW 8.9 billion, and Ocon has expanded its business area to theme parks.
Despite the fact that the original characters were created decades ago, the recent huge success of these
businesses is attributed by technological developments and diversification of distribution channels.
NCSOFT Corporation was founded in 1997 by its current CEO Taek-Jin Kim. Today NCSOFT is now one of the
world leaders on development and publishing of massively multiplayer online games with paid-in capital of KRW
10 billion. NCSOFT gained and established its position with its flagship product "Lineage", the first successful
internet-based online game in Korea. Thanks to high penetration rates of fast broadband in Korea, Lineage
became popular very quickly, and the company soon launched following games: Lineage 2 and AION. Over the
past years NCSOFT has established its position in the Asian, North American and European markets.
Since its launch in 1998 Lineage, the first Korean online game, has earned KRW 130 billion annually on average,
and the accumulated sales in 2013 amounted to more than KRW 2 trillion. As Lineage has mainly contributed to
NCSOFT’s growth in sales and size, Taek-Jin Kim appeared on the Forbes’ list of “World’s Billionaires 2011:
Record Year For The Richest” (1140th out of 1211 richest people in the world).
YG Entertainment was established in 1996 as original name of Hyun Entertainment by its current representative
Hyun-Suk Yang. Today it is one of the largest entertainment companies, home to well-known artists in Korea such
as 1TYM, Big Bang and 2NE1. In 2012, it produced PSY's Digital Single "Gangnam Style" and has earned its
world-wide recognition and big revenues. "Gangnam Style" was promoted mainly through YouTube, the world's
most popular web site for uploading and sharing videos, and it has spread out with a number of video remakes
and parodies throughout the world. After the launch of its official music video, uploaded on YouTube in July 2012,
Gangnam Style won Guinness World Record for the most liked video in Youtube history in September 2012 and
has been viewed over 2 billion times in May 2014.
YG Entertainment has been expanding its business models to various content markets such as concerts,
broadcasts, games and advertisements while focusing on its main music business.
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: In Korea the legal issue of copyrights is regulated by the Copyright
Act that was first passed in 1957 and amended several times.
Recent evolution: The Copyright Act has been amended several times since its enactment in order to
reflect the changing environment in technology and copyright-intensive industries as follows:
•
Jan. 28, 1957: Enactment of the Copyright Act of Korea.
•
Dec. 31, 1986: Introduction of internationally recognised regimes in order to join international
conventions such as Universal Copyright Convention.
•
Dec. 30, 1989: Amendments following the amendment to the Government Organisation Act.
•
Dec. 27, 1990: Amendments following the amendment to the Government Organisation Act
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
271 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
Mar. 8, 1991: Change of names of relevant Acts following the enactment of the Library Promotion
Act
•
Mar. 6, 1993: Amendments following the amendment to the Government Organisation Act
•
Jan. 7, 1994: Extension of protection term of copyright and neighbouring rights and imposition of
more rigorous penalties, etc.
•
Mar. 24, 1994: Change of names of relevant Acts following the amendment to the Libraries and
Reading Promotion Act
•
Dec. 6, 1995: Amendments following the WTO TRIPS, in preparation for the accession to Berne
Convention
•
Dec. 13, 1997: Introduction of a hearing system for such cases as revocation of copyright
collective management services
•
Jan. 12, 2000: Introduction of the right of interactive transmission, expansion of the scope of
immunity for libraries, and imposition of more rigorous penalties, etc.
•
July 10, 2003: Provision of sui generis protection of database producers and clarification of the
scope of responsibilities of online service providers
•
Oct. 16, 2004: Granting of the right of interactive transmission to performers and phonogram
producers
•
Oct. 4, 2006: Change of names of relevant Acts following the amendment to the Library Act
•
Dec. 28, 2006: Introduction of the concepts of public transmission and digital sound transmission.
Introduction of the Copyright Commission. Introduction of orders to collect, discard, delete and
suspend illegal reproductions, etc.
•
Feb. 29, 2008: Amendment following the amendment to the Government Organisation Act
•
Mar. 25, 2009: Granting of immunity to the National Library of Korea (collection of online
materials for preservation purposes). Clarification of the scope of specialised recording formats for
the exclusive use by visually impaired persons, etc. Introduction of the right to claim remuneration
for public performances for performers and phonogram producers.
•
Apr. 22, 2009: Integration of the Copyright Act and the Computer Program Protection Act.
Establishment of the Korea Copyright Commission. Strengthening of measures to prevent illegal
online reproductions, etc.
•
July 7, 2009: Change of names of relevant Acts following the amendment to the Act on the
Advancement of Newspapers, etc.
•
June 30, 2011: Recognition of the Korea-EU Free Trade Agreement
•
Dec. 2, 2011: Recognition of the Korea-US Free Trade Agreement
•
July 16, 2013: Amendment of Reproduction for Visually Impaired Persons
•
Dec. 30, 2013: Amendment of free use of Public Works
Duration of copyright: In general copyright protection in Korea ends 70 years following the death of
the last living author. Different rules exist for the term of protection of performances, phonograms and
broadcasts: 70 years after the performance, 70 years after the publication, and 50 years after the
broadcasting, respectively
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
272 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Institutional setting: The Ministry of Culture, Sports and Tourism (MCST) is the main institution in
charge of copyright-related issues in Korea. Within MCTS there are four dedicated divisions:
•
Copyright Policy Division Its tasks include: Improving copyright-related laws and institutional
systems; Supervising the Korea Copyright Commission; Promoting copyright education and
public awareness campaigns; Enhancing copyright protection overseas.
•
Copyright Industry Division Its tasks include: Laying the foundation for transaction of copyright
(registration/authentication); Standardising copyright protection and management technologies;
Guiding and supervising copyright management organisations and copyright brokerage
organisations; Managing copyright statutory license and copyright donation systems, etc.
•
Copyright Protection Division (including five regional offices) Its tasks include: Crackdown on
distribution of illegal reproductions online/offline; Support for the operation of the Copyright
Protection Center; Ordering suspension of online transmission of illegal reproductions or their
deletion and imposing fines and taking other appropriate measures; Support for the development
and operation of illegal reproduction tracking and management system, etc.
•
Culture and Trade Team Its tasks include: Planning/coordination of trade policies in the cultural
sector including FTAs/ Cooperation with copyright-related international organisations such as the
World Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO), foreign governments and agencies
Other relevant institutions include: the Korean Copyright Commission (KCC), the Presidential
Council on Intellectual Property and the Copyright Protection Center.
The Korean Copyright Commission (KCC) is a government-funded public entity whose organisation
is based on the Copyright Act. According to Article 113, the KCC has the following functions, among
others: i) conciliation of disputes; ii) deliberation on matters concerning the rates and amounts of fees and
royalties for the copyright management service providers; iii) promotion of fair use of works; iv)
recommendation for corrective measures; v) statutory licensing and copyright registration entrusted by the
MCST.
The Presidential Council on Intellectual Property, established on July 28, 2011, is in charge of the
following policy areas: i) formulation, review, evaluation and modifications of national IPR strategies in
Korea and the following action plans, ii) allocation of financial resources related to IPR policies.
The Copyright Protection Center focuses on offline copyright piracy. Although the MCST has the
sole administrative power to crack down online and offline piracy, it delegates the offline enforcement
power to the Center 214.
Database protection: The Copyright Act provides sui generis protection for non-original databases.
The protection of database producers is defined in the Chapter 4 of the Copyright Act. A database producer
shall hold the rights to reproduce, distribute, broadcast or interactively transmit of a whole or considerable
part of his database.
Limitations and exceptions: In Korean copyright legislation limitations and exceptions are provided
in Articles 23 to 36 and 101ter of the Copyright Act 215. These include the following cases:
•
Use in political speeches, judicial proceedings, for the purpose of school education, exam
questions, news reporting, articles and editorials.
•
Quotations.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
273 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
Public performance and broadcasting for non-profit purposes.
•
Private use.
•
Reproduction in libraries.
•
Reproduction for Visually Impaired Person
•
Ephemeral Sound or Visual Recordings by Broadcasting Organizations
•
Exhibition or Reproduction of Work of Art
•
Temporary Reproduction in the Course of Use of Work
•
Fair use provisions.
•
Use by means of translation.
It should be highlighted, that these limitations and exceptions clauses do not waive author’s moral
rights.
Orphan works: The Copyright Act has a statutory licensing scheme for orphan works entitled "Use
of Works in Which the Owner of Author’s Property Rights Is Unknown."
In particular, Article 50 stipulates that if any person, despite considerable efforts made in accordance
with the criteria prescribed by the Presidential Decree, cannot identify the owner of author’s property
rights in a work made public (except foreigners’ works) or his residence and therefore is unable to obtain
the authorization of the author for its use, may use the work by obtaining approval from the MCST as
prescribed by the Presidential Decree, and depositing remuneration according to the criteria as determined
by the MCST. The authority of the MCST in respect of statutory licensing is delegated to the KCC.
The simplified statutory licensing scheme was introduced in April, 2012 and enforced in October
2012. Its main purpose was to facilitate the use of orphan works. The amendment to the Presidential
Decree provides that the certain efforts by the MCST may replace the considerable efforts on the part of
the intended user.
Copyright registration: Copyright registration is not mandatory in Korea, although it provides
certain procedural benefits in case of a dispute or infringement. Copyright can be registered on-line at the
Korea Copyright Commission and costs KRW 23.600 (USD 23) for most works except for software, where
the on-line registration costs KRW 53.600 (USD 52). Off-line registration is possible and is on average
KRW 10.000 (USD 10) more expensive.
Over the past five years the total number grew steadily at 6.75% average annual growth rate, from 24
225 registrations in 2009 to 31 462 registrations in 2013 (See Figure 5.34). Among all the registered works
in 2013, computer programs have the highest share of 43.5% followed by artistic works (25%) and literary
works (11%). For more detailed statistics on Korean copyright registrations see Table 5.5.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
274 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.34.
Copyright registrations in Korea (2009-2013)
35,000
30,000
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
2009
2010
Total number of registrations
Table 5.5.
2011
Computer programmes
2012
Artistic works
2013
Literary works
Copyright registrations in Korea
2009-2013; by subject matters and by right-holders
Type of work
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Literary
2,309
3,776
3,612
3,742
3,658
Musical
987
1,387
1261
1,446
1,430
Theatrical
27
25
20
24
58
Artistic
5,075
4,632
5,179
7,092
7,938
Architectural
117
84
246
57
131
Photographic
378
447
281
507
447
Cinematographic
238
676
374
505
626
Diagrammatic
400
742
567
528
545
1,082
1,330
1,562
1,823
1,981
279
451
907
645
572
11,856
12,483
13,858
14,101
13,690
-
-
-
-
-
93
24
3
30
1
1,366
705
230
565
323
18
86
54
101
62
Type of right holder
Individuals
Legal persons
Others
2009
6,759
17,187
279
2010
9,904
16,201
743
2011
10,516
16,678
960
2012
11,622
16,334
3,210
2013
12,220
15,843
3,399
Total
24,225
26,848
28,154
31,166
31,462
Works
Compilation
Derivative
Computer program
Others
Performance
Photogram
Database
Enforcement: The main agencies in charge of copyright enforcement in Korea are the Prosecutor's
Office and the National Police. The law on special police power with the amendments in 2003 and 2008
gave a mandate to the MCST to counter online copyright piracy. Furthermore, customs authorities have a
special role in combating pirated trade, according to Korean Customs Act 216.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
275 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Current debate
Summary of recent debates: The public debate on “copyrights in the age of the Internet” seems to be
relatively advanced in Korea. It has been taking place for several years, and gathered numerous experts
from the government, academia, think tanks, industry and civil society. Currently the following general
themes are being debated:
•
Implementation of the Free Trade Agreements between Korea and the USA and between
Korea and the EU.
•
Legal issues related to the so-called smart environment.
•
Use of copyrighted works that originate from government agencies and public institutions.
•
Criminal components of copyright violation.
Industry associations: There are 12 main industry associations in Korea. All of them are
government-authorized organizations that manage copyrights in areas of music, literary, media
(broadcasting and press), cinematographic and public works. These associations are:
•
Music industry: Korea Music Copyright Association, Recording Industry Association of Korea,
Federation of Korean Music Performers
•
Literary works: Korea Reproduction and Transmission Rights Association, Korean Society of
Authors, Korean TV and Radio Writers Association, Korea Scenario Writers' Association
•
Media: Korea Broadcasting Performers' Association, Korea Press Foundation
•
Cinematographic
Association
•
Public work: Korea Culture Information Service Agency
industry: Movie Distributors Association of Korea, Korean Film Producers
For more details on these associations and their activities see the Appendix.
Industry best practices: Three relevant examples can be mentioned in the context of industry best
practices in Korea: the graduate response scheme by Korean Internet service providers (ISPs), Korea
Online Newspaper Association and its “Usage Rules for Online Content" and the "Guide on Cost
Estimation for Software Project" by Korea Software Industry Association.
Korea enjoys one of the highest rates of high-speed Internet penetration in the world, which is clearly
beneficial for Internet users and for many parts of the industry. Unfortunately, it is also an partial enabler
for online piracy. This triggers counter-actions of Korean government (see enforcement) and pushes the
industry to develop a set of best-practices. In 2009 a graduated response system was introduced targeting
heavy uploaders who repeatedly make illegal copies available on the Internet. According to this system, the
MCST issues orders to Korean ISPs to warn the on-line pirates and/or delete illegal copies. After the third
warning, the MCST after deliberation by the KCC orders the ISPs to suspend their access for not more than
6 months.
The Korea Online Newspaper Association (KONA) is a non-profit organization with the members of
the major online news companies in Korea that endeavours to protect its members' rights, in particular the
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
276 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
rights related to the copyright law. In 2005 KONA published the "Usage Rules for Digital News" and in
2008 "Usage Rules for Online Content".
The "Usage Rules for Digital News" has been revised twice in order to reflect the amendments to the
copyright law and to the developments of the online news market since the first publication in 2005. They
provide information for readers on how to legally use digital news. They recall that digital news is
protected by the copyright law and readers should use digital news according to the terms and conditions
applied by the KONA. They address such issues as "copy and paste", hyperlinks, Rich Site Summary
services, online communities, etc.
The "Usage Rules for Online Content" outlines rights and obligations for subscribers to the online
news contracts. They deal with various issues ranging from the scope of use and modification of online
content to the expiration of use and copyright protection measures.
The Korea Software Industry Association (KOSA), consists of 1,200 IT and software companies, and
promotes a fair trading ecosystem. It proposes a proper cost estimation services for software projects
summarized in its "Guide on Cost Estimation for Software Project". The Guide was made for software
companies who are interested in participating in software development projects conducted by government
agencies and public institutions in a effort to enhance competitiveness of domestic software industries. It
proposes the cost estimation methods at the stages of project planning, software development and system
maintenance and management. Explanations and comments are provided with illustrations and
hypothetical examples.
Korea country study annex: Collective Management Organisations in Korea
Korea Music Copyright Association
The Korea Music Copyright Association (KOMCA) was established in 1964 to protect the rights and
interests of music copyright holders. It was authorized to provide copyright collective management
services on February 23, 1988 and manages the right of public performance, the right of broadcasting, the
right of interactive transmission and the right of reproduction of musical works. The KOMCA collected
copyright royalties worth KRW 108.7 billion in 2011 and KRW 111.5 billion in 2012, despite global
economic downturn and extreme industrial slowdown in Korea. The numbers of its members and collective
management agreement signatories broke through the 15,000 mark and the number of works under its
collective management amounts to as many as 1 725 733, indicating its strong position as a music
copyright collective management organisation.
The KOMCA is striving to develop various new means of royalty collection and to expand royalty
rates on a continual basis. As indicated by the new establishment of films’ performance royalties, the
organization continues to achieve not only quantitative growth, but also substantive qualitative growth. In
the case of broadcasting royalties for terrestrial broadcasting stations, the royalty rate has been expanded to
1.2%, compared to the past, while it has been decided that revenues from endorsement would be included
in the scope of revenues. It has also decided to settle VOD and webcasting service royalties under separate
regulations, doing its utmost to protect the rights of its members. The KOMCA also prepares to begin
collecting royalties for the use of music by UCCs, Blogs and Cafes on the Internet.
In addition, on December 4, 2012, during training sessions for representatives from countries in Asia
and Latin America, as well as from Myanmar, Bhutan, Laos, Sri Lanka, Bangladesh, Mongolia, Nepal,
India, Cambodia, Kenya, and Senegal, a project implemented in partnership with the World Intellectual
Property Organization (WIPO).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
277 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Recording Industry Association of Korea
The Recording Industry Association of Korea (RIAK) was established in 2001 to protect the rights
and interests of phonogram producers. It was authorized to provide copyright collective management
services by the then Minister of Culture and Tourism on March 17, 2003 and has provided collective
management of 260,000 songs owned by 2 217 members.
In addition to collective management of neighbouring rights for phonogram producers, the RIAK
collects and distributes remuneration for 1.92 million songs of 3,000 phonogram producers, as it was
designated as an organization to collect broadcasting remuneration for commercial phonogram in 2001, as
an organisation to collect remuneration for digital audio transmission of phonogram in 2008 and as an
organization to receive remuneration for performances for commercial phonogram in 2009 by the Minister
of Culture, Sports and Tourism. Furthermore, the RIAK is proactively involved in copyright protection
activities and crackdown on illegal audio sources.
Meanwhile, in May 2011, the RIAK was transferred with the Korea Music Data Center project from
the Korea Creative Content Agency (KOCCA). The project is aimed at promoting citizens’ right to culture
by collecting and classifying data on Korean music in a systematic manner and building online and offline
data centre. Permanent and special exhibition halls and a data centre were opened on the first floor and the
first basement floor in the Olympic Hall. In 2011, the “Korean Wave Soaring into the World” was staged
and Nam In-su Special Exhibition was featured in 2012.
Federation of Korean Music Performers
The Federation of Korean Music Performers (FKMP) was established in June 1988 to protect and
manage neighbouring rights of performers. It was authorised to provide copyright collective management
services on November 14, 2000 by the then Minister of Culture and Tourism and has managed
neighbouring rights of performers since then.
In addition to collective management services, the FKMP collects and distributes remuneration for
music performers as it was designated as an organisation to collect remuneration for broadcasting of
phonograms for sale in October 1988, an organisation to collect remuneration for digital sound
transmission in 2008, and an organisation to collect remuneration for public performances of phonograms
for sale in 2009.
As of December 31, 2012, the FKMP had 6,307 performers as its individual members and six special
members, including the Korea Singers' Association, the Singers' Committee of the Korea Entertainers
Association, the Korea Recording Musician Association, the Korean Traditional Music Association, the
Music Association of Korea and the Korea Musicians Association. Its major activities include collection
and distribution of copyright royalties and various remunerations, protection of rights and interests of
music performers and improvement of their status, protection of rights of Korean music performers in
foreign countries and publicity campaigns on neighbouring rights.
Korea Reproduction and Transmission Rights Association
The Korea Reproduction and Transmission Rights Association (KRTRA) was established on July 1,
2000 to protect the rights of copyright holders and publishers and promote the fair use of copyrighted
works through collective management of rights on reprography and transmission of literary works on
behalf of rights holders. The KRTRA was authorised as a copyright collective management organisation on
November 14, 2000 and has copyright collective management organisations and related organisations as its
members. The KRTRA has distributed full-amounts of collected fees to right holders since 2009, and the
KRTRA carries out crackdown activities throughout the year to promote the legitimate use of works and
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
278 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
eliminate illegal reproductions. For example, in collaboration with the MCST and the Copyright Protection
Center, it performs joint crackdowns on photocopying businesses in university areas during new school
semesters (March and September) to protect rights holders.
In addition to its main responsibility of providing copyright collective management services, the
KRTRA has been designated as an organisation to collect remuneration from libraries (October 17, 2003)
pursuant to Article 31 of the Copyright Act and remuneration for school education purposes (March 13,
2008) pursuant to Article 25 of the Copyright Act. Since then, it has collected and distributed
remunerations from those organisations.
As standards on remuneration for reproduction, performance, etc. for school education purposes
pursuant to Paragraph 2 of Article 25 of the Copyright Act was notified (the Minister of Culture, Sports
and Tourism Notification No.2011-017, April 28, 2011), in 2011, the KRTRA organised workshops and
produced guidebooks to provide information on the remuneration system aimed to collect and distribute
remunerations on the use of copyrighted works for school education in schools such as universities,
making concerted efforts to help the remuneration system for school education purposes to take root at an
early date.
Besides, the Association also made multifaceted efforts to locate copyright holders to facilitate the
distribution of collected remunerations. In the case of remunerations on textbooks, in particular, it has
undertaken a variety of projects, including online and offline advertising campaigns, production of
database and catalogue for images used in textbooks to found out the right holders.
Korean Society of Authors
The Korean Society of Authors (KOSA) was officially launched on July 28, 1988 after receiving
approval by the Ministry of Culture and Public Information (currently, the MCST) for corporation
establishment on July 13, 1988.
KOSA was authorised to provide copyright collective management services on March 16, 1989. Since
then, it has managed copyrights of literary, dramatic, artistic and photographic works. In addition to
copyright collective management, the main activities of KOSA include copyright infringement
investigation and pursuit of legal remedies and public awareness activities by holding seminars and
publishing publications. As of December 2012, KOSA had 3,462 members (including 82 groups).
In 2012, the KOSA signed an MOU with the Korea Writers’ Association (KWA) on April 18 to
promote the rights of wider circles of copyright holders, while pursuing mutual cooperation with various
organisations, including the Korea Novelists Association and the Korea Children’s Writers Association, to
provide support for defending the rights and interests of writers.
As the free-of-charge e-Book publication project supported by KOSA starting from 2011 was wellreceived among its members, the KOSA published 200 works in e-book format by 2012. It is also
preparing for a project to provide support for publication of paper books for its members.
Meanwhile, KOSA members visited Japan to sign a mutual management agreement to distribute
Korean literary works overseas and distribute overseas works in Korea and held discussions on the mutual
management agreement with the Japan Writers’ Association.
Korean TV and Radio Writers Association
The Korean TV & Radio Writers Association (KTRWA) was established in 1962 to promote the
rights and interests of TV broadcast writers who work in general fields of the broadcasting industry,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
279 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
including TV dramas, documentaries, entertainment, radio and translation, and contribute to the
development of national culture through the growth of broadcasting literature and exchanges. It was
authorised to provide copyright collective management services on September 20, 1988.
Korea Scenario Writers' Association
The Korean Scenario Writers' Association (KSWA) was established to protect the rights and interests
of scenario writers, offer collective manage services such as licensing and management of scenario works
on behalf of scenario writers, and contribute to the development of scenarios. It was authorised to provide
copyright collective management services on September 12, 2001 when its name was the Cinematographic
Scenario Writers Association. As it was renamed as the KSWA in November 2002, it launched copyright
collective management and brokerage services in full swing.
The KSWA is engaged in various activities associated with its members and industry, including
activities to protect the copyright of its members, research into scenarios, prize awards to meritorious
members, and projects to promote the welfare of its members. In 2011, it hosted the Korea Scenario
Contest with prize money worth KRW 100 million, contributing to invigoration of the film industry,
including copyright projects.
The KSWA also has trained a number of scenario writers through its affiliated organisation, the
"Scenario Writers Training Institute" established in 1992. In 2011, scenario writers of the institute's 37th
and 38th class were trained in the training institute. A scenario contest and prize-awarding ceremony were
also held at the training institute. And, KSWA recommended members for the Korean Film Council, and
sectorial subcommittees of the Korea Media Rating Agency.
Korea Broadcasting Performers' Association
The Korea Broadcasting Performers' Association (KPBA) was established in August 2001 to protect
neighbouring rights of broadcasting performers, including TV actors, voice actors, comedians and MCs. It
was authorised by the then Ministry of Culture and Tourism to provide copyright collective management
services on February 20, 2002.
The KBPA signed a special agreement on the use of neighbouring rights of its members with
terrestrial and cable TV broadcasting companies pursuant to Paragraph 3 of Article 100 of the Copyright
Act. Based on the agreement, it collects neighbouring right license fees that arise when broadcasting
organisations reproduce, distribute, broadcast or interactive transmit broadcast programs where its
members make an appearance from them and distributes royalties to its members.
As of 2012, the KBPA has signed MOUs with terrestrial broadcasting companies such as KBS, MBC,
SBS, EBS, OBS and nine regional private broadcasting companies, as well as 47 programme providers
(PP) for cable TV programs, to protect the rights of its members.
Furthermore, it understands that the level of protection of performers’ rights stipulated in Article 100
(3) of the Copyright Act lags behind compared with protection cases of developed countries, posing an
obstacle to protection and promotion of the rights of performers. Hence, it has been vigorously engaged in
policy activities to address this issue. Apart from such efforts, the KBPA is engaged in a variety of other
activities to protect the rights of its members in practical terms, while expanding welfare programs for its
members. It is also striving to sign a special agreement with newly launched general-programming cable
TV channels.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
280 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Korea Press Foundation
In February 2010, the Korea Press Foundation (KPF, formerly the Korea Press Center in 1962 with
two other organisations) was launched with the consolidation of the former Korea Press Foundation, the
Newspaper Circulation Institute and the Newspaper Promotion Commission.
The KPF was authorised to provide copyright collective management services on June 7, 2006. As of
the end of 2011, it manages the copyright of news works of 69 media of 59 media companies. Starting
from 2011, 13 media from seven leading media companies such as Chosun, JoongAng, and DongA have
joined the KPF's services in the form of agency or brokerage services, so the number of media companies
under the management of the KPF amounts to 82 media from 66 media companies.
In 2012, the KPF organised a contest for a campaign against infringement of news copyright (UCC,
newspaper advertising, slogan categories) to raise awareness of copyright protection. It also published
research reports on the “digital news contents market and copyright” and “a study on news copyrightrelated systems and legal precedents in foreign countries.” It also identified practices of using news-related
copyrighted works and established a permanent monitoring system to prevent copyright infringement,
while launching public awareness campaigns to protect news copyright via various media such as
newspapers, radio and the Internet. It posted news copyright protection advertising on more than 100
occasions in the newspapers of its member companies. The KPF has also developed educational video
materials on protection of news copyright for the general public and youth, respectively, and plans to
utilise them for public awareness campaigns on news copyright this year.
In order to facilitate paid use of news, the KPF has provided integrated new package products for
central government agencies, doubling the scale of paid use of news by state organisations, compared to
the previous year. It is endeavouring to expand the supply of the paid package products to local
governments and public organisations.
As a result of such efforts, the KPF’s news copyright collective management project has been selected
by the World Association of Newspapers and News Publishers (WAN-IFRA), which is the world’s largest
press organisation in which the world’s newspaper publishers and editors participate, as an exemplary
business model in recognition of its contribution to boosting market value of news and its success story
was presented globally.
Movie Distributors Association of Korea
The Movie Distributors Association of Korea (MDAK) was established in 1999 to promote seamless
and fair use of cinematographic works and establish their distribution order. It was authorised to provide
copyright collective management services on November 9, 2005.
The MDAK manages the right of public performance of cinematographic works and mainly grants
licenses to DVD theatres nationwide for performance of cinematographic works.
The MDAK's main activities include collective management of cinematographic works, collection
and distribution of copyright royalties, crackdown on illegal cinematographic reproductions for copyright
protection, protection of the rights and interests of its members, information management to facilitate the
use of cinematographic works, suggestions for related bills and public awareness campaigns. In 2010, it
established subcommittees to promote the development of the film distribution and home entertainment
industries and pursued various solutions to address problems in respective industries.
In 2012, for an example of the activities, the MDAK carried out guidance and public awareness
activities to eliminate the use of illegal cinematographic works and prohibit unauthorised use in libraries,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
281 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
accommodation establishments and bath houses. It also raised public awareness of copyright protection for
cinematographic works. In the same year, the MDAK had 54 companies as its members, including regular
members and special members. It also has six staff members, consisting of directors including the president
and staffs at the secretariat that deals with management of copyright of cinematographic works, strategic
planning and collection of royalties.
Korean Film Producers Association
The Korean Film Producers Association (KFPA) was established in February 1994 as a consultative
body for currently active film producers in Korea. It joined the International Federation of Film Producers
Associations (FIAPF) in 2001 and was authorised to provide copyright collective management services by
Ministry of Culture and Tourism in 2005.
As an association of film producers, the KFPA is engaged in a wide range of projects involving
Korea's film industry, including prevention of illegal reproduction and copyright protection, facilitation of
the secondary market in the film industry, labour-management negotiations in the film industry and
development of a standard contract form, and pursuit of rationalisation measures of the industrial structure,
thereby contributing to both qualitative and quantitative growth of the film industry in Korea. As of the end
of 2011, the KFPA had 65 companies as its members.
Korea Culture Information Service Agency
Korea Culture Information Service Agency (KCISA) was established in 2002 mainly to provide
cultural information management services.
With the private sector’s rising demand for works owned by public institutions, the Korea Database
Agency (KDB) has been authorised to provide copyright collective management services to accelerate their
utilisation. The KCISA has been in charge of the services since the KDB transferred them to the KCISA in
2013.
Unlike private collective copyright management organisations that mainly engage in licenses of
copyrighted works and collection of royalties on behalf of their members, the KCISA is a copyright
collective management organisation in the public sector, so it focuses on distributing free copyrighted
works based on the intentions of public institutions to promote the use of public copyrighted works by the
private sector.
In addition to collective management of public copyright, the KCISA also strived to promote the use
of public copyrighted works by the private sector. As part of this effort, in February 2012, it introduced the
Korea Open Government License (KOGL) system, which is a system to permit the free use of public
copyrighted works, and distribution is fully under way.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
282 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Poland
State of the Internet
In recent years access to broadband networks and the Internet has steadily increased in Poland. In
addition, further deployments of fibre networks have taken place. Overall, however, broadband penetration
rates and the deployment of fibre in Poland are still at an early stage in Poland and below the OECD
averages (see Figure 5.35).
Figure 5.35.
Broadband penetration rates in Poland
2002-2013, per 100 inhabitants
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2009
2008
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD)
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Poland)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Poland)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
More recently there has been rapid and substantial growth in mobile broadband access in Poland,
opening up new communication possibilities to people as they are away from a fixed-line connection.
Mobile broadband penetration has grown to over 60% in Poland, which is at a comparable level with the
OECD average that has grown to more than 70% (Figure 5.36).
Figure 5.36.
Mobile broadband subscriptions in Poland
2009-2013, per 100 inhabitants
80.00
70.00
60.00
50.00
40.00
30.00
20.00
10.00
0.00
2009-Q4
2010-Q2
2010-Q4
2011-Q2
2011-Q4
Poland
2012-Q2
OECD
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
2012-Q4
2013-Q2
2013-Q4
283 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
Value added: Over the past years copyright-intensive industries in Poland have demonstrated overall
stable performance 217. Between 2008 and 2011 the total share of the copyright-based industries within the
Polish economy remained virtually stable, accounting for 4.17% of Poland’s GDP in 2011 (Figure 5.37).
Figure 5.37.
Added value of copyright-Intensive industries in Poland
2002-2012, % of GDP (left axis)
4.5%
4.4%
4.3%
4.2%
4.1%
4.0%
3.9%
2008
2009
2011
2010
% of GDP
Source: Eurostat SBS database and EPO-OHIM (2013).
Employment: The total number of people employed in copyright-intensive industries represented
2.3% of all employed by Polish industry. Between 2008 and 2011, the overall share of people employed in
copyright-intensive industries in total industry employees remained virtually stable. The total employment
reported some fluctuations over that period. In 2011 it amounted to 315,000, which was slightly less than
the volume of employment in these industries in 2008 (Figure 5.37).
Figure 5.38.
Employment in copyright-intensive industries
volume of employment (right axis) and % of total employment (left axis)
3.0%
350,000
345,000
2.8%
340,000
335,000
2.6%
330,000
325,000
2.4%
320,000
315,000
2.2%
310,000
2.0%
300,000
305,000
2008
2009
% of total employment
2010
2011
Number of employees
Source: Eurostat SBS database and EPO-OHIM (2013).
Copyright-intensive industries and the Internet economy: In Poland, there are several services that
offer legitimate access to copyrighted content in the Internet. Given that Polish language is mostly spoken
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
284 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
in Poland only, hence content in Polish language is like to be demanded mostly in Poland, the activity of
these services should be analysed in the context of the type of provided content: whether it is mostly
foreign or domestic (Polish) content. Concerning foreign content, the main problem faced by most local,
Polish services are the large costs of access to legitimate foreign content. Given the relatively moderate
size of Polish market, this significantly increases the per-user costs, and it turn in favours global players
such as iTunes of Spotify that are able to get access to content at a much more favourable per-user rate.
In the on-line music market in Poland main active services include: Muzo 218, Muzodajnia, 219 iplay 220
and Empik 221. In addition, some companies offer single music files or ringtones online, or rely on music in
another way (e.g. as suppliers of technological solutions relating to music, especially in the
telecommunications sector). These services include Soho.pl 222, Polish Sound 223, NuPlays 224, Mobila 225,
Papla 226, PlaytheMusic 227, Mood 228, Wind Mobile 229. It should be mentioned that on the music market,
some services, such as Sound Park 230 or MegaTotal.pl 231, specialise only in music that is not offered by
“big labels”. Sound Park addresses its offer to individual artists and independent labels. Megatotal.pl is the
first Polish platform of music-related crowd funding and an online store 232 offering mostly music that was
financed through the platform 233.
Most major music streaming service providers are now also present in the Polish market: iTunes,
Deezer, WiMP, Spotify, YouTube and (since June 2014) Google Play Music. Proceeds from digital music
sales rose by 45% in 2013, reaching 33,3 mln zlotys, which amounts to 15% of the total music market. 234
Concerning Polish video-on-demand (VOD) market, there are several active legitimate services, that
can be divided into four main categories:
•
Services related to a TV station or a telecom company (Ipla.pl, TVP.pl, TVNplayer.pl,
Orange.pl/vod).
•
Services related to web portals (Vod.pl, Kinoplex.pl).
•
Services related to movie distributors (Cineman.pl, Strefavod.pl).
•
Independent services (Iplex.pl, Vodeon.pl).
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: In Poland the legal issue of copyrights is regulated by the Act of
4 February 1994 on copyright and related rights 235, by the Act of 27 July 2001 on databases protection 236
and by several specific regulations of the Ministry of Culture and National Heritage (MKiDN). In shaping
its internal law Poland is obliged to take into account relevant Directives of the European Parliament and
of the Council in its legislation, such as: the Directive on the term of protection of copyright and certain
related rights (2006/116/EC), the directive on the harmonisation of certain aspects of copyright and related
rights in the information society (Copyright Directive, 2001/29/EC) and the directive on the enforcement
of intellectual property rights (Enforcement Directive, 2004/48/EC).
Additionally the important issue of Internet intermediary liability is regulated in the Act of 18 July
2002 on Providing Services by Electronic Means (articles 12-15), which transposes into the Polish legal
system the directive on certain legal aspects of information society services, in particular electronic
commerce, in the Internal Market (eCommerce Directive, 2000/31/EC)
Recent evolution: Over the past 20 years there have been several amendments of the Copyright Act,
mostly implementing EU Directives. The main ones, introduced in 2011 focused on improvement of
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
285 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
activities of collective rights management associations (transparency improvement) and functioning of the
Copyright Commission – the arbitrary body whose main activity is to set tariffs used by collective
management organisations.
Duration of copyright: In Poland copyright protection generally ends 70 years following the death of
the last living author.
Institutional setting: Polish Ministry of Culture and National Heritage (MKiDN) is the main actor in
the area of legislative works and awareness building campaigns in the area of copyright and related rights.
In addition, in 2000 the horizontal, Intergovernmental Team for Counteracting Infringements of
Copyright and Related Rights was established, to coordinate efforts related to enforcement of various IPRs
in Poland. The Team, on the basis of the analysis of state of the art in the domain of enforcement of
copyright and related rights, is in course of preparing the new “Programme for the protection of copyright
and related rights” which is to be adopted in the second part of 2014 and which will be in force for the
tenure of 3 years.
The Ministry of Administration and Digitisation, set up in 2011, is responsible for the legal
framework concerning information society services and hence is involved in developing copyright policy
in the digital domain.
Furthermore, some other Ministries and government agencies are active in order to ensure effective
functioning of the copyright protection, especially in the area of enforcement. These include:
•
Ministry of Justice, The Office of the General Prosecutor, National School of the Judiciary and
Public Prosecution: in the area of improvement of the efficiency of prosecutions and proceedings
concerning copyright protection.
•
Ministry of Internal Affairs and Ministry of Finance (Customs Service): in relation to limiting
infringements of copyright and related rights, and other intellectual property rights in the markets.
•
Patent Office, Minister of Science and Higher Education, Minister of National Education: in
relation to conducting educational activities towards the development of social and legal awareness
in the area of copyright and related rights and their role in the development of economy and
knowledge based society
•
Ministry of Internal Affairs, Ministry of Finance, The Office of the General Prosecutor, Minister of
Justice, Minister of Foreign Affairs: in relation to enhancing international cooperation in the
relevant areas of protection of copyright and related rights.
Database protection: If a database meets the originality criteria, it is treated as a literary work and is
protected under the law of copyright. In addition, all databases in the Poland are protected by Act of 27
July 2001 on databases protection, which followed the directive 96/9/EC of the European Parliament and
of the Council, of 11 March 1996 on the legal protection of databases.
Limitations and exceptions: Private personal use (dozwolony użytek osobisty) includes creation of
backup or reserve copies, or creation of copies for sharing them with family and close friends.
Poland has implemented wide spectrum of limitations and exceptions that are in conformity with the
international copyright law and European directives. These include: limitations and exceptions for libraries
and archives, educational institutions, access to and processing of the information by press and media,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
286 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
citation, incidental reproduction of works, public exhibition, limitations and exceptions for the benefit of
disabled persons.
Orphan works: This area in is not explicitly regulated yet. Projects of new legislation that will
comply with the directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on certain permitted uses of
orphan works (2012/28/EU) are currently debated.
Copyright registration: Copyright cannot be registered in Poland. There are works under way on
introducing the registration procedure for orphan works in conformity with the EU Directive
(2012/28/EU).
Enforcement: In Poland IPR enforcement is a both a civil and a criminal matter.
In civil proceedings an infringement should be pursued by the right holder in court. It should be
mentioned that the enforcement of intellectual property rights through civil law in Poland is often
criticised. In particular, the following problems are highlighted:
•
Lengthy and excessive proceedings.
•
Lack of specialised courts and judges with substantive preparation and inconsistent case law
(decisions of a significant discrepancy based on the same legal grounds and factual evidence).
•
Inefficient system of enforcement; problems concern both the execution of final judgments and
provisions on the protection of claims and information obligations (Articles 80 and 105 of Act on
Copyright and Related Rights).
•
Lack of qualified experts.
•
Other problems related to the IPR enforcement on the internet, such as lack of best practices
governing the violations on the Internet and responsibilities of Internet service providers.
In criminal law there is a number of offences relating to copyright, most of them contained in the Act
of 4 February 1994 on copyright and related rights (articles 115-119). Apart from the traditional offences
such as false authorship claim or unauthorised reproduction and dissemination of protected works these
also include offences of manufacture or possession of products or components intended for the
circumvention of effective technical protection measure and failing to provide evidence. For the law
enforcement authorities to take action the right holder must usually file an official petition, but some of the
more serious ones allow for ex officio enforcement action.
Current debate
Summary of recent debates: The Copyright Forum (Forum Prawa Autorskiego) is the main platform
for debates on the current copyright framework in Poland and its planned reforms. The Forum was
established in 2013 by the Minister of Culture and National Heritage; it gathers around 80 institutions,
associations and organisations of different origin including the representatives of creative, collective
management organisations, chambers of commerce, cultural institutions and users and other related nongovernmental organisations. Every meeting of the Forum is paralleled with written consultations, and all
the outcomes are published online 237. So far Forum has debated on: orphan works, out-of-commerce
works, limitations and exceptions, public lending right, criminal sanctions; the Forum also joined copyright
consultations organised by the European Commission. The results of these discussions will be incorporated
into the legislative work on the new amendment of the Copyright Act that is going to start in 2014.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
287 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
The copyright debate in Poland gained prominence after large scale protests broke out against the
Anti-Counterfeiting Trade Agreement in early 2012, when thousands of protesters took to the streets
around the country.
Industry associations: In Poland, there are several associations, industry chambers and collective
management organisations of copyright-intensive industries in Poland. They carry out a number of
activities, including: i) collective rights management ii) countering copyright infringement (intelligence
collection, collaboration with relevant enforcement authorities, and training of public authorities) iii)
awareness raising campaigns in the area of copyrights, and iv) data collection.
The most active industry-specific ones include: Izba Wydawców Prasy (Chamber of Press Editors),
Polska Izba Książki (Polish Chamber of Books), and Krajowa Izba Producentów Audiowizualnych
(National Chamber of Audiovisual Producers).
The main active collective management organisations include: ZAiKS (mostly literature and music),
SAiW Copyright Polska (books, visual arts and photography), SFP (audio-visaul works), REPROPOL
(press editors), STOART (music artists), SAWP (music authors), ZPAV (music producers), ZASP (actors),
SARP (architects), ZPAV (photography), ZPAP (visual works).
Other relevant associations include: Stowarsyssenie Kreatywna Polska (Creative Poland), Swiąsek
Kompozytorów Polskich (the Union of Polish Composers), and the Legalna Kultura foundation (copyright
awareness-rising activities).
A number of non-profit non-gevernmental organisations are active in the debate. These include:
Fundacja Nowoczesna Polska (Modern Poland Foundation), Centrum Cyfrowe: Projekt Polska (Digital
Centre: Project Poland), Fundacja Panoptykon (Panoptykon Foundation), Fundacja Wolnego I Otwartego
Oprogramowania (Free and Open Software Foundation).
Switzerland
State of the Internet
In recent years access to broadband networks and the Internet has constantly increased in Switzerland.
In terms of fixed broadband, penetration levels have been growing constantly and are well above the
OECD average, reaching maturity. In addition, further deployments of fibre networks have taken place.
Overall, however, deployment of fibre in Switzerland is still below the OECD average (see Figure 5.38).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
288 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.39.
Broadband penetration rates in Switzerland
2002-2013, per 100 inhabitants
50
40
30
20
10
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Switzerland)
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (Switzerland)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
More recently there has been stable, substantial growth in mobile broadband access in Switzerland,
opening up new communication possibilities to people as they are away from a fixed-line connection.
Mobile broadband penetration has grown to almost 65% in Switzerland, which is slightly below the OECD
average (Figure 5.39).
Figure 5.40.
Mobile broadband subscriptions in Switzerland
2009-2013, per 100 inhabitants
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
2009-Q4
2010-Q2
2010-Q4
2011-Q2
2011-Q4
Switzerland
2012-Q2
2012-Q4
2013-Q2
2013-Q4
OECD
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
Unfortunately, to our knowledge the existing databases do not permit to draw an internationallycomparable picture of Swiss copyright-intensive industries. However, the Federal Statistical Office
provides some information of the performance of the publishing, audio-visual and broadcasting industries
(categories 58-60). These industries seem to be closely, although not fully representing, the core copyrightintensive industries as proposed by WIPO (2003).
Over the past fifteen years these industries in Switzerland have demonstrated somehow mixed
performance, with a peak in 2005. Over that period the Swiss industry grew at average rate of 0.3%,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
289 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
although at a slower rate than the overall economy. In absolute terms Swiss industries that rely on
copyrights contributed on average CHF 3.1 billion to the Swiss GDP over the past ten years (Figure 5.40).
In 2011 the total contribution calculated for these industries was CHF 3 billion, accounting for 0.3% of
Switzerland’s GDP.
Figure 5.41.
Added value of copyright-intensive industries* in Switzerland
1997-2011, CHF millions, at current prices (right axis) and % of GDP (left axis)
1.5%
1.3%
1.1%
0.9%
0.7%
0.5%
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
% of GDP (left axis)
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
3500
3400
3300
3200
3100
3000
2900
2800
2700
2600
Total Value Added (right axis)
*) Publishing, audio-visual and broadcasting activities (categories 58-60)
Source: Swiss Federal Statistical Office, Industry and services production and turnover indicators;
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: “Swiss Federal Act on Copyright and Related Rights”. Adopted in
1992 (CopA).
Recent evolution: The Swiss copyright Act (CopA) has been amended several times in order to
support a functioning market in the digital environment. These amendments implemented some
international treaties and standards (such as the WIPO Copyright Treaty and the WIPO Performances and
Phonograms Treaty), lead to creation of the Monitoring Office for Technological Measures (see below),
and included new copyright exceptions and limitations (for example relating to temporary copies and to the
use of works by people with disabilities).
Duration of copyright: For software, copyright protection generally ends 50 years following the
death of the last living author. For other creative works copyright protection generally ends 70 years
following the death of the last living author.
Institutional setting: The main institution in Switzerland in charge of the copyright-related issues is
the Swiss Federal Institute of Intellectual Property. It acts as advisory to the Federal Council and other
federal administrators in all area of intellectual property and represents Switzerland at the international
level in these areas. It also supervises the collecting societies.
The Federal Arbitration Commission for the Exploitation of Copyrights and Related Rights
(Arbitration Commission) 238 is responsible for approving the tariffs of the collective rights management
organisations.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
290 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
The Monitoring Office for Technological Measures checks how technological measures are affecting
the lawful use of works and whether public interests are being impacted. In addition, the office acts as an
intermediary between those who apply technological measures and user and consumer groups and helps as
needed in finding partnership solutions.
Database protection: There is no sui generis protection of databases in Switzerland. Original
databases qualify for protection under copyright law.
Limitations and exceptions: In Switzerland the Copyright Act (CopA) defines precisely when a use
of copyrighted contend can be done legally without rights holders’ authorisations. This includes the
following cases: private use (Art. 19, CopA); decoding of computer programs (art. 21, CopA);
dissemination of broadcast works (Art. 22, CopA); use of broadcasting organisations' archived works (Art.
22a, CopA); use of orphan works (Art. 22b, CopA); making available broadcast musical works (Art. 22c,
CopA); compulsory licence for the manufacture of phonograms (Art. 23, CopA); archive and backup
copies (Art. 24, CopA); temporary copies (Art. 24a, CopA); copies for broadcasting purposes (Art. 24b,
CopA); use of works by people with disabilities (Art. 24c, CopA); quotations (Art. 25, CopA); museum,
exhibition and auction catalogues (Art. 26, CopA); works on premises open to the public (Art. 27, CopA);
and reporting current events (Art. 28, CopA).
Orphan works: According to Article 22b of CopA use of orphan works is permitted in Switzerland
and is subject to prior notification of collective societies. This Article only applies to phonograms or
audiovisual fixations.
Copyright registration: Copyright cannot be registered in Switzerland.
Enforcement: In Switzerland, rights owners can file complaints in civil or criminal court against
infringers. The cantonal courts are responsible for judging the infringement cases.
Current debate
Summary of current debate: In 2012, the Minister of Justice mandated a stakeholders’ working
group (AGUR12) to work on the modernisation of copyright law with regard to ongoing technical
developments. The working group AGUR12 gathered representatives of: creative artists, producers, users,
consumers, and representatives of the Swiss Federal Administration. In its final report that was published
in December 2013, the AGUR12 recommends the adoption of a package of measures aimed at increasing
the attractiveness of legal offers and simplifying the fight against piracy. These actions include
improvement of consumer information, expanding and thus increasing the attractiveness of legal offers,
simplifying the fight against piracy, enhancing the efficiency and transparency of collective societies, and
adapting the limitations and exceptions to copyright to recent developments. 239
Industry associations: There are many industry associations in Switzerland, including: AudioVision
Schweiz (audio visual industry), Schweizerische Interpretengenossenschaft (performers), Schweizer
Buchhändler- und Verleger-Verband (publishers and booksellers), Suisseculture (culture and media), Swiss
Music Promoters Association (music industry), Verband Schweizer Medien (media), Simsa (the Swiss
Internet Industry Association). In addition international associations, such as IFPI or BSA also have Swiss
members and Swiss regional services.
These associations carry out a number of activities, including: (i) lobbying, stakeholder coordination
and engaging in public debate about copyright, (ii) countering copyright infringement (intelligence
collection, collaboration with relevant enforcement authorities), (iii) awareness raising campaigns in the
area of copyrights, and (iv) data collection.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
291 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Industry best practices: The Hosting Code of Conduct (HCC) has been adopted by Simsa in early
2013 in order to counter the growth of traffic in illegal content, and in order to introduce industry standard
that would strengthen legal security. The notice-and-take-down procedure introduced in the HCC contains
principles of conduct that are already incorporated in self-regulatory instruments adopted by European and
international associations of Internet Service Providers.
The United Kingdom
State of the Internet
In recent years access to broadband networks and the Internet has steadily increased in the UK. In
addition, further deployments of fibre networks have taken place. Overall, broadband penetration rates are
well above the OECD averages. However, the deployment of fibre in the UK is still at an early stage and
below the OECD averages (see Figure 5.41).
Figure 5.42.
Broadband penetration rates in the UK
2002-2013, per 100 inhabitants
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD)
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (the UK)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (the UK)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
More recently there has been rapid and substantial growth in mobile broadband access in the UK,
opening up new communication possibilities to people as they are away from a fixed-line connection.
Mobile broadband penetration has grown to almost 80%, which is way above the OECD average that has
grown to 72% (Figure 5.42).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
292 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.43.
Mobile broadband subscriptions in the UK
2009-2013, per 100 inhabitants
90.00
80.00
70.00
60.00
50.00
40.00
30.00
20.00
10.00
0.00
2009-Q4
2010-Q2
2010-Q4
2011-Q2
2011-Q4
The UK
2012-Q2
2012-Q4
2013-Q2
2013-Q4
OECD
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
Value added: Over the past years copyright-intensive industries in the UK have demonstrated a better
overall performance compared to the overall economy. 240 Between 2008 and 2012 the total volume of the
copyright-based industries has increased by 15.6 %, compared with an increase of 5.4 % for the UK
Economy as a whole. In 2012 the total contribution calculated for the core copyright-based industries in the
UK was 5.2% of total GDP.
Employment: In 2012 the total number of people employed in copyright-intensive industries
represented 5.6% of all employed by the UK industry. Between 2011 and 2012, the overall share of people
employed in copyright-intensive industries in total industry employees grew by 8.6%.
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: In The UK the legal issue of copyrights is regulated by the Copyright,
Designs and Patents Act 1988 (“CDPA”). In addition the UK is obliged to take into account relevant
Directives of the European Parliament and of the Council in its legislation, such as: the Directive on the
term of protection of copyright and certain related rights (2006/116/EC) or the directive on the
harmonisation of certain aspects of copyright and related rights in the information society (Copyright
Directive, 2001/29/EC)
Recent evolution: Within the past 20 years the main amendments originated from application of EU
directives [see EU case study].
The most recent amendments took place on 29 October 2014, implementing the EU Orphan Works
Directive (2012/28/EU) as well as a domestic orphan works licensing scheme.
Duration of copyright: For literary, dramatic, musical or artistic work copyright protection ends 70
years from the end of the year in which the author died. For sound recordings, it ends 50 years from the
end of the year of making or, if it is published or made available during this time, 70 years from the end of
the year in which it was published or made available. For film it ends 70 years from the end of the calendar
year of the death of the last to die of the principal director, the author of the screenplay, the author of the
dialogue, or the composer of music specially created for and used in the film, or if there are no such
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
293 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
people, 50 years from the end of the year of making. For broadcasts, it ends 50 years from the end of the
year the broadcast was made. For published editions: 25 years from the end of the year of publication.
Institutional setting: The UK Intellectual Property Office (IPO) has responsibility for copyright
policy in the UK.
In addition, The Department for Culture, Media and Sport (DCMS) has an interest in supporting and
promoting cultural copyright-intensive industries, and leads on some areas of broadcasting policy and on
internet regulation, including measures against copyright infringement online.
The National Archives has responsibility for state-owned copyright.
Database protection: If a database meets the originality criteria, it is treated as a literary work and is
protected under the law of copyright. In addition, all databases in the UK are protected by “Database
Right” (implementation into UK law the provisions of the Database Directive), which gives the owner the
right to prevent copying and unauthorised use of the database.
Limitations and exceptions: The UK provides for a number of exceptions to copyright, for purposes
such as research and private study, education, and for the benefit of libraries and archives. Some are
restricted to ‘fair dealing’ with a work, and some come into being only when there is no licensed
alternative available.
Recent amendments to UK copyright legislation (on 1 June and 1 October 2014) introduced a new set
of copyright exceptions, in order to give a number of sectors a legal framework fit for the digital age.
These exceptions allow uses such as personal copying for private use, parody, caricature and pastiche,
quotation making accessible format copies of protected material for disabled people, text and data mining
for non-commercial research, and fair dealing with copyright content for educational purposes.
Orphan works: The Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on certain permitted
uses of orphan works (2012/28/EU) sets out common rules to provide for an exception to copyright law
allowing the digitisation and online display of orphan works. The UK implemented the Directive in
October 2014. .
Additionally, at the same time the UK introduced an orphan works licensing scheme which permits
anyone to reproduce any type of orphan work in any media for commercial and non-commercial use. This
means that providing the applicant has shown that they have undertaken a sufficiently diligent search, on
payment of a market rate licence fee they will be granted a non-exclusive licence to reproduce an orphan
work for up to 7 years (which can be renewed), for use within the UK only (as the UK Government cannot
grant licences for use in other jurisdictions). Licence fees are held in case the right holder/s reappear 241. To
increase the chances of any right holder/s being found, a freely accessible and searchable orphan works
register is available. The register lists details of orphan works licence applications, works that have been
licensed as orphan and applications that have been refused.
Copyright registration: Copyright registration is not required in the UK; it is not offered by the IPO.
Enforcement: The UK’s IP enforcement agencies are the following:
•
The IPO is responsible for all IP policy, including IP enforcement policy (in its Copyright and
Enforcement Directorate). The IPO also has an intelligence capability in the form of an
Intelligence Hub, which collaborates closely with law enforcement agencies. The IPO is not an
enforcement agency itself, and is not able to take legal action against any sort of IP infringement.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
294 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
The UK’s Trading Standards (TS) are responsible for tackling both piracy and counterfeiting at a
local level. The TS eCrime Centre focuses on internet scams, include the large scale distribution
of pirated and counterfeit goods.
•
The Police tackle IP crime at a local, regional, national and international level. The Police IP
Crime Unit (PIPCU), which is based in the Economic Crime Directorate of the City of London
Police, is dedicated to tackling serious, organised IP crime online, in the form of both piracy and
counterfeiting. (It was established in September 2013, and the IPO is providing £2.56m in
funding over the first two years (2013-15)).
•
The UK’s National Crime Agency (NCA) (established in October 2013), targets all IP crime
through its Economic Crime Command.
•
Under EU Directive 608/2013, concerning customs enforcement of intellectual property rights,
HM Revenue and Customs (HMRC) and Border Force have the power to detain copyright and
trademark infringing material.
Current debate
Summary of recent debates: The public debate on “copyrights in the age of the Internet” seems to be
relatively advanced in The UK. It has been taking place for several years, and gathered numerous experts
from the government, academia, think tanks, industry and civil society 242.
Currently, the prominent issues under discussion include:
•
The debate on potential reform of copyright at the EU level, with the emphasis on completing the
Digital Single Market 243.
•
The UK’s copyright reforms, within the EU copyright framework. Many of these changes were
recommended by the Hargreaves Review of IP and Growth (2010-11) 244.
•
Meeting the enforcement challenges of digital technologies (including the internet)
Industry associations: There are many industry associations in the UK, including in the music, film
and television, books and periodicals, visual arts, videogames and broadcasting sectors. 245 These
associations carry out a number of activities, including: i) collective rights management, ii) countering
copyright infringement (intelligence collection, collaboration with relevant enforcement authorities,
training of public authorities), iii) awareness raising campaigns in the area of copyright, and iv) data
collection.
Industry best practices There are several relevant industry initiatives in the area of copyright,
including:
•
Codes of Practice for Collecting Societies: Following extensive consultation with Government,
most UK collecting societies have established a system of self-regulation through industry codes of
practice that broadly align with the UK Government’s minimum standards.
•
Digital Copyright Exchange: A Copyright Hub has been established by the industry to provide a
gateway for finding information about UK copyright. The project received initial funding from the
Government, but the sector is now working with the Connected Digital Economy Catapult (CDEC)
to further develop the project.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
295 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Voluntary Copyright Alert Programme (VCAP), an industry initiative that seeks to find a voluntary
solution to provide a mass warning scheme to ISP consumers whose accounts show evidence of alleged
infringing activity. Industry is still involved in the commercial negotiations to create such a scheme;
however the UK Government remains fully supportive of VCAP.
The United States
State of the Internet
Access to broadband networks and the Internet has constantly increased in the United States in recent
years. In terms of fixed broadband, penetration levels have been growing constantly and are above the
OECD average. In addition, further deployments of fibre networks have taken place. However, overall
deployment of fibre in the United States is still at an early stage and is below the OECD average
(see Figure 5.43).
Figure 5.44.
Broadband penetration rates in the US
2002-2013, per 100 inhabitants
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (US)
Broadband Total subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (US)
Broadband Fibre/LAN subscriptions per 100 inhabitants (OECD total)
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
More recently there has been rapid and substantial growth in mobile broadband access in the United
States, opening up new communication possibilities to people as they are away from a fixed-line
connection. Mobile broadband penetration has grown to more than 100% in the United States, which is
way above the OECD average that has grown to 72% (see Figure 5.44).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
296 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.45.
Mobile broadband subscriptions in the US
2009-2013, per 100 inhabitants
120.00
100.00
80.00
60.00
40.00
20.00
0.00
2009-Q4
2010-Q2
2010-Q4
2011-Q2
2011-Q4
United States
2012-Q2
2012-Q4
2013-Q2
2013-Q4
OECD
Source: OECD Broadband Portal
Copyright-intensive industries: Market overview
Value added: Over the past ten years the copyright-intensive industries in the United States have
demonstrated generally good performance. Between 2000 and 2012 the total volume of the copyrightbased industries grew either by 70% or 80%, depending on methodology chosen 246. In absolute terms
the US copyright-intensive industries reported moderate rates of growth, and contributed over the past ten
years on average USD 590 billion to the American GDP (Figure 5.45).
Figure 5.46.
Added value of copyright-Intensive industries in the United States
2000-2012, USD billion (according to Siwek-IIPA methodology and ESA-USPTO methodology)
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
ESA-USPTO methodology
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
Siwek-IIPA methodology
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis' Industry Accounts database.
In 2012 the total contribution calculated for the core copyright-based industries was USD 764 billion
according to the ESA-USPTO methodology, or USD 781 billion according to the Siwek-IIPA study which
uses the statistical methodology as presented in WIPO (2003) 247. The core copyright-based industries
accounted for 4.7% (4.8%, respectively) of the US GDP (Figure 5.46).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
297 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.47.
Added value of copyright-Intensive industries in the United States
2000-2012, % of GDP (according to Siwek-IIPA methodology and ESA-USPTO methodology)
5.0%
4.5%
4.0%
3.5%
3.0%
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
ESA-USPTO methodology
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
Siwek-IIPA methodology
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis' Industry Accounts database.
Employment: The total number of people employed in 2011 in copyright-intensive industries
represented 3.0% of all employed by the US industry according to the ESA-USPTO methodology (3.2%
according to Siwek-IIPA-methodology) (Figure 5.47), which seems almost unchanged compared to the
shares reported in 2000. Between 2000 and 2011, the total employment in copyright-intensive industries
reported some fluctuations and amounted to 4.17 million of employees in 2011 (4.5 million according to
Siwek-IIPA methodology) (Figure 5.48).
Figure 5.48.
Employment in copyright-intensive industries
2000-2011; % of industry employment (according to Siwek-IIPA methodology and ESA-USPTO methodology)
4.5%
4.0%
3.5%
3.0%
2.5%
2.0%
1.5%
1.0%
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
ESA-USPTO methodology
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
Siwek-IIPA methodology
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis' Industry Accounts database.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
298 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Figure 5.49.
Volume of employment in copyright-intensive industries
2000-2011; thousands of employees, (according to Siwek-IIPA methodology and ESA-USPTO methodology)
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
ESA-USPTO methodology
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
Siwek-IIPA methodology
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis' Industry Accounts database.
Business cases: The Internet significantly affects the American copyright-intensive industries by reshaping existing business models and introducing brand new ways of business operation. In 2011, ecommerce reached 16% of the US business sector turnover (excluding some service activities), doubling
with respect to the beginning of the decade (OECD, 2012). The efficiencies enabled by the Internet have
also been welcomed by copyright-intensive industries, and there are numerous business initiatives that took
the advantage of the Internet as the distribution channel. Two prominent anecdotal examples include
Apple’s iTunes and Netflix, whose current business models are based on the digitisation of content (see
Box 5.8.).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
299 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Box 5.8. Creative businesses on the Internet in the United States: Apple’s iTunes and Netflix
iTunes is an umbrella term that refers to an online digital media store operated by Apple and to compatible pieces
of software (media player, media library, etc.) that were developed by Apple. The iTunes store opened in 2003,
and offers music, apps, TV shows, audiobooks, podcasts, movies, etc. All the downloaded content becomes
immediately available on Apple devices, such as iPhone, iPod or iPad. After some years of tremendous growth
iTunes became in 2010 the biggest online music store in the world.
Netflix is a provider of two types of services: streaming of media on-demand and DVD-by-mail. Netflix started in
1997 as an online DVD rental, with flat fees and an extensive and successful personalised video-recommendation
system. In 2007 Netflix began to expand its market by introducing video on demand via the Internet. While the
number of on-line DVD rentals fell from 2006 onwards, the on-line streaming turned out to be successful. As of
mid-2014, Netflix reports global streaming subscribers at 50 million (36 million in the United States) (See Box
Figure 5.1). Netflix revenues from streaming yield at that period USD 1.04 billion (USD 800 million in the United
States) (See Box Figure 5.2).
Box Figure 5.1: Netflix. Total members in various market segments (in thousands).
40,000
35,000
30,000
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
3.2012
6.2012
9.2012
Domestic Streaming.
12.2012
3.2013
6.2013
International Streaming.
9.2013
12.2013
3.2014
Domestic DVD.
Box Figure 5.2: Netflix. Revenues in various market segments (in thousands USD).
USD 900,000 K
USD 800,000 K
USD 700,000 K
USD 600,000 K
USD 500,000 K
USD 400,000 K
USD 300,000 K
USD 200,000 K
USD 100,000 K
USD 0 K
3.2012
6.2012
9.2012
Domestic Streaming
12.2012
3.2013
6.2013
International Streaming
9.2013
12.2013
3.2014
Domestic DVD
Source OECD, based on data from Netflix 2011 annual report
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
300 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Legal landscape
Current copyright legislation: Copyright protection in the United States is governed by the
Copyright Act of 1976 and all subsequent statutory amendments and enactments thereto 248.
Recent evolution: A number of revisions to the US copyright legislation have sought to reflect
contemporary uses of technology, to cope with changes in socio-economic landscape and to comply with
evolving international obligations 249.
One of the most profound amendments over the past 20-year period was the Digital Millennium
Copyright Act (DMCA) that was passed in 1998. The DMCA implemented the WIPO Copyright Treaty
and the WIPO Performances and Phonograms Treaty, including obligations pertaining to technological
protection measures and rights management information. It also addressed a number of other significant
issues, including, inter alia, the creation of qualified limitations on liability for online service providers
when engaged in certain categories of activities, and exceptions pertaining to computer maintenance and
repair, digital preservation by libraries/archives and ephemeral recordings 250.
In addition to legislation, the U.S. courts also have a role in interpreting U.S. copyright law to address
legal, technological, and other changes.
Duration of copyright: In the United States the copyright law automatically protects a copyrightable
work that is created and fixed in a tangible medium of expression on or after January 1, 1978, from the
moment of its creation and gives it a term lasting for the author’s life plus an additional 70 years. This is
only a general rule, however. Depending on when a work was created and whether a work was published,
different rules may apply. Additionally, the terms of protection for anonymous, pseudonymous and works
made for hire also constitute exceptions to the basic life plus seventy term 251.
Institutional setting: The Copyright Act vests all administrative functions and duties under the Act
with the Register of Copyrights as well as important copyright policy functions (as director of the U.S.
Copyright Office) 252. The Register’s duties include advising Congress on national and international issues
relating to copyright; providing information and assistance to federal agencies and the judiciary relating to
copyright; participating in meetings of international intergovernmental organisations and meetings with
foreign government officials relating to copyright issues; and conducting studies and programs regarding
copyright 253. In addition to the Copyright Office, copyright-related issues are within the scope of interest of
other federal agencies. According to statute, the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO, as
part of the Department of Commerce, principally advises the President and the entire Executive Branch of
the federal government on matters concerning intellectual property law and policy (including copyright).
Other parts of the Department of Commerce dealing with copyright-related issues include: Economic and
Statistics Administration (ESA), International Trade Administration (ITA), National Telecommunications
and Information Administration (NTIA), and the National Institute of Standards and Technology (NIST).
In addition, the USTR provides advice on the trade-related aspects of intellectual property, including
copyright. The Office of International Intellectual Property Enforcement of the Department of State works
closely with other federal departments and agencies on intellectual property issues along with providing
advice to economic, commercial and public diplomacy officers at U.S. embassies around the world.” The
Computer Crime and Intellectual Property Section (CCIPS) of the Criminal Division of the United States
Department of Justice is the federal entity that prosecutes intellectual property crimes.
Database protection: In the United States there is no sui generis database right. This means that
databases do not receive a separate protection, but copyright protection extends to the selection,
coordination or arrangement of information when it is done so in a manner that is adjudged original enough
to receive protection 254.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
301 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Limitations and exceptions: The U.S. Copyright Act includes six exclusive rights in Section 106,
including rights to reproduce the works, to prepare derivative works, to distribute copies, etc.
Concerning exceptions and limitations, Sections 108-122 of the United States Copyright Act
enunciate specific limitations and exceptions for a range of uses of copyrighted material that do not require
authorisation from a right holder. The United States codified the judge-made fair use doctrine in its
Copyright Act in 1976 in Section 107. This section includes a list of various purposes for which the use of
a particular work may be considered fair, such as criticism, comment, news report, teaching, scholarship,
and research. It also sets out four factors to be considered in determining whether a particular use is fair.
These factors are: i) the purpose and character of the use, including whether such use is of a commercial
nature or is for non-profit educational purposes; ii) the nature of the copyrighted work; iii) the amount and
substantiality of the portion used in relation to the copyrighted work as a whole, and iv) the effect of the
use upon the potential market for or value of the copyrighted work 255.
It should be mentioned that the fair use doctrine is buttressed by decades of case law jurisprudence
and any given litigation takes place against this backdrop; in litigation, fair use must be raised as an
affirmative defence to infringement. Section 107 does not comprise all of the copyright exceptions under
the Copyright Act, however, as noted above.
Orphan works: Orphan works are not explicitly regulated in the United States.
At the request of Congress, the U.S. Copyright Office finalised a report on Orphan Works in
January 2006. Legislation was introduced in Congress in 2006 and again in 2008, but was never ultimately
enacted into law. The proposed legislation generally tracked the recommendations of the Copyright Office
and would have limited remedies available under the Copyright Act when a user is unable to locate the
copyright owner or other appropriate rights holder after conducting a good faith reasonably diligent search;
been applicable on a case-by-case basis; and permitted the copyright owner or other rights holder later to
collect reasonable compensation from the user, but not statutory damages or attorney’s fees.
Currently the United States Copyright Office is studying issues involving both orphan works and
mass digitisation. Public comments have been received, and the Copyright Office recently held a public
roundtable meeting on this topic on March 10-11, 2014 256. The Office expects to release a report and
recommendation on these issues to Congress sometime in 2015.
Copyright registration: In the United States an author can file an application for a copyright
registration. Registration is voluntary and it is not a condition of copyright protection that copyright
protection begins automatically at the moment of authorship (i.e., the moment an original work is fixed in a
tangible medium of expression). Nonetheless, registration provides the copyright owner with certain
benefits, including permitting a copyright owner to pursue statutory damages in civil lawsuits and
providing prima facie evidence in court of the validity of the copyright claim.
For works of U.S. origin, an author must register before filing an infringement suit in court.
Moreover, for all works, statutory damages and attorney’s fees are available if registration is made within
three months after publication of a work or prior to infringement. Other benefits of registration can be
found at the U.S. Copyright Office website 257.
Enforcement: In the United States, copyright infringement is generally a civil matter, which the
copyright owner must pursue in federal court. Under certain circumstances, the infringement may also
constitute a criminal misdemeanour or felony, which would be prosecuted by the U.S. Department of
Justice. Indeed, the Justice Department recently issued the fourth edition of its Manual on Prosecuting IP
Crimes 258.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
302 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Current debate
Summary of current debate: Over the last 20 years, there has been a robust discussion of a broad
range of issues related to “copyright in the age of the Internet” involving the U.S. Government, industry,
academia, and civil society. The Green Paper on Copyright, Creativity, and Innovation in the Digital
Economy (“Green Paper”) issued in July 2013 by the Department of Commerce Internet Policy Task Force
(IPTF) provides an overview of the developments during that time period.
Most recently, following a call for congressional review of the copyright law from Register of
Copyrights Maria Pallante in early 2012 259, the House Subcommittee on Courts, Intellectual Property and
the Internet is currently undertaking a comprehensive review of U.S. copyright law. Several hearings
following the Register’s original testimony in March 2013 have been held (as of early June 2013),
including the following: A Case Study for Consensus Building: The Copyright Principles Project (May
2013); Innovation in America: The Role of Copyrights (July 2013); Innovation in America: The Role of
Technology (August 2013); The Role of Voluntary Agreements in the U.S. Intellectual Property System
(September 2013); The Rise of Innovative Business Models: Content Delivery Methods in the Digital Age
(November 2013); The Scope of Copyright Protection (January 2014); The Scope of Fair Use (January
2014); Section 512 of Title 17 (March 2014); Preservation and Reuse of Copyrighted Works (April 2014);
Compulsory Video Licenses of Title 17 (May 2014); and First Sale under Title 17 (June 2014); Music
Licensing Under Title 17 (June 2014); Moral Rights, Termination Rights, Resale Royalty, and Copyright
Term (July 2014); Copyright Remedies; and Chapter 12 of Title 17 (September 2014) and Copyright Issues
in Education and for the Visually Impaired (November 2014) 260. More hearings will be scheduled at least
through the first half of 2015.
In addition, the U.S. Copyright Office regularly undertakes studies at the request of Congress and also
under its own initiative. Recent reports for Congress have included a report on Small Copyright Claims
(September 2013) 261 and on Resale Royalties (December 2013) 262. The Office also has open dockets,
requesting public comment in advance of completing reports to Congress on issues such as orphan works
and mass digitisation (mentioned above), the right of making available 263, and issues related to music
licensing 264. Preparation of such reports involves requests for public comment as well as public roundtable
hearings. These policy efforts are in addition to the Office’s ongoing work, which includes registration
issues, a review of the copyright recordation system, an inquiry into technological updates, an updated fee
study, and associated regulatory rulemakings 265.
The IPTF of the U.S. Department of Commerce also brought together the technical, policy, trade,
economic, and legal expertise of several government agencies to produce the “Green Paper” 266. The Green
Paper "provides a lens through which to assess current policy related to copyright and the Internet,
identifying important issues that are being addressed by the courts and those that are ripe for further
discussion and development of solutions." The paper checks whether the “current balance of rights,
exceptions and responsibilities – crafted, for the most part, before the rapid advances in computing and
networking of the past two decades – is still working for creators, rights holders, service providers, and
consumers” 267.
As a follow up to the Green Paper, the IPTF will be holding a series of roundtable discussions in 2014
on:
•
the legal framework for the creation of remixes;
•
the relevance and scope of the first sale doctrine in the digital environment; and
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
303 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
•
the appropriate calibration of statutory damages in the contexts of: i) individual file sharers and
ii) secondary liability for large-scale infringement.
The purpose of the roundtables was to seek additional input from the public in locations around the
country in order for the Department to have a complete and thorough record upon which to make
recommendations.
In the Green Paper, the Department also stated its intention to establish an open multi stakeholder
forum aimed at improving the operation of the notice and takedown system for removing infringing
content from the Internet under the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA). The goal is to provide a
collaborative forum through which stakeholders will identify best practices and/or develop voluntary
agreements for improving the technical operation of the DMCA notice and takedown system. A wide
variety of the notice and takedown system’s users are participating, including right holders and individual
creators, service providers, consumer and public interest representatives, and technology companies.
Best practices: Much of the content industry’s enforcement initiatives in the United States seem to
concentrate in the area of online copyright enforcement; to be clear, however, the content industries do
continue to engage in anti-piracy actions that involve their content that is not online in nature. Indeed, most
online copyright enforcement actions in the United States are handled through civil litigation. Copyright
owners have at their disposal a range of possible tools, including lawsuits against the primary infringer as
well as actions based on theories of secondary liability. There are also procedures apart from litigation for
removing infringing content from the Internet 268. Also, as mentioned above, certain copyright infringement
cases have resulted in federal criminal prosecutions.
Considerable progress in curbing online infringement has been made in recent years through
stakeholder co-operation. One such example can be found in the voluntary agreement reached between
rights holders and internet service providers to implement the Copyright Alert System. The first report
marking the one year anniversary of the implementation of this system was recently released 269.
The Green Paper notes that most online copyright enforcement is handled through private action.
Copyright owners have at their disposal a range of possible tools, including lawsuits against the primary
infringer or based on theories of secondary liability, as well as procedures short of litigation for removing
infringing content from the Internet 270.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
304 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
ANNEX. COPYRIGHT-INTENSIVE INDUSTRIES
Australia
Table A 5.1.: Copyright-intensive Industries in Australia
Industry (ANZSIC, 2006, Revision 2.0)
Newspaper, Periodical, Book and Directory Publishing
Software Publishing
Motion Picture and Video Activities
Sound Recording and Music Publishing
Radio Broadcasting
Television Broadcasting
Internet Service Providers and Web Search Portals
Data Processing, Web Hosting and Electronic Information Storage Services
Libraries and Archives
Other Information Services
Advertising Services
Other Professional, Scientific and Technical Services
Creative and Performing Arts Activities
Amusement and Other Recreation Activities
Printing and Printing Support Services
Reproduction of Recorded Media
Newspaper and Book Retailing
Entertainment Media Retailing
Telecommunications Services
Data Processing, Web Hosting and Electronic Information Storage Services
code
Group 541
Group 542
Group 551
Group 552
Group 561
Group 562
Group 591
Group 592
Group 601
Group 602
Group 694
Group 699
Group 900
Group 913
Group 161
Group 162
Class 4244
Class 4242
Group 580
Group 592
Canada
Table A 5.2.
Core Copyright-Based Industries in Canada
Industry (NAICS description)
NAICS code
Publishing Industries (except Internet)*
* includes 5111 Newspaper, periodical, book, and directory publishers, and 5112 Software
publishers
Motion picture and sound recording industries **
** includes 5121 Motion picture and video industries and 5122 Sound recording industries
Radio and television broadcasting
Cable and other subscription programming
Computer systems design and related services (software and databases)
Advertising, public relations, and related services
Performing arts, spectator sports and heritage institutions
511
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
512
5151
5152
5415
5418
71A
305 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
The European Union, Italy and Poland
Table A 5.3.
Copyright-intensive Industries in the European Union, Italy, and in Poland
Industry (NACE description)
Book publishing
Publishing of newspapers
Publishing of journals and periodicals
Other publishing activities
Publishing of computer games
Other software publishing
Motion picture, video and television programme production activities
Motion picture, video and television programme post-production activities
Motion picture, video and television programme distribution activities
Motion picture projection activities
Sound recording and music publishing activities
Radio broadcasting
Television programming and broadcasting activities
Wireless telecommunications activities
Computer programming activities
Computer consultancy activities
Computer facilities management activities
Other information technology and computer service activities
Web portals
News agency activities
Other information service activities n.e.c.
Advertising agencies
Media representation
Specialised design activities
Photographic activities
Translation and interpretation activities
Performing arts
Support activities to performing arts
Artistic creation
Library and archives activities
Other amusement and recreation activities
Printing of newspapers
Other printing
Pre-press and pre-media services
Binding and related services
Reproduction of recorded media
Retail sale of books in specialised stores
Retail sale of newspapers and stationery in specialised stores
Retail sale of music and video recordings in specialised stores
Wired telecommunications activities
Satellite telecommunications activities
Other telecommunications activities
Data processing, hosting and related activities
Other reservation service and related activities
NACE code
58.11
58.13
58.14
58.19
58.21
58.29
59.11
59.12
59.13
59.14
59.20
60.10
60.20
61.20
62.01
62.02
62.03
62.09
63.12
63.91
63.99
73.11
73.12
74.10
74.20
74.30
90.01
90.02
90.03
91.01
93.29
18.11
18.12
18.13
18.14
18.20
47.61
47.62
47.63
61.10
61.30
61.90
63.11
79.90
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
306 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Industry (NACE description)
Photocopying, document preparation and other specialised office support activities
Cultural education
Operation of arts facilities
Activities of amusement parks and theme parks
Activities of professional membership organisations
NACE code
82.19
85.52
90.04
93.21
94.12
Source: EPO-OHIM (2013).
Japan
Table A 5.4.
Copyright-intensive Industries in Japan
Industry (Japan Standard Industrial Classification; Rev. 12, November 2007)
Broadcasting
Information Services
Internet based services
Video Picture Sound Information, character Information Production and distribution
(except. 4161 and 4169)
Advertising
Libraries
Establishments engaged in administrative or ancillary economic activities
(share corresponding to category 8212)
Design services
Authors and Artists
Establishments engaged in administrative or ancillary economic activities
(share corresponding to category 726 and 727)
Photographic Studios
Establishments engaged in administrative or ancillary economic activities
(share corresponding to category 746)
Performances (except otherwise classified), Theatrical Companies)
Establishments engaged in administrative or ancillary economic activities
(share corresponding to category 802)
Printing and allied Industries
Semiconductor memory media
Optical discs and magnetic tapes and discs
Establishments engaged in administrative or ancillary economic activities
(share corresponding to category 2831 and 2832)
Source: http://www.stat.go.jp/english/index/seido/sangyo/san07-3a.htm#g
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
code
38
39
40
41
73
8212
820
726
727
720
746
740
802
800
15
2831
2832
280
307 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Korea
Table A 5.5.
Economic Activity (Class)
Press and Literature
Authors, writers, translators
(including one person business)
Copyright-intensive Industries in Korea
KSCIC
Code
1010101
1010102
Newspapers
News and feature agencies etc.
Magazines/periodicals
Book publishing
Cards, maps, directories and
other published materials
Pre-press, printing, and postpress of books, magazines,
newspapers, advertising
materials
1010200
1010300
1010401
1010402
1010501
1010502
1010599
1010600
1010701
1010702
1010797
1010703
1010704
1010798
Wholesale and retail of press and
literature
1010801
1010802
1010803
1010804
Libraries
1010900
Music, Theatrical Productions & Operas
Composers, lyricists, arrangers,
1020101
choreographers, writers,
1020102
directors, performers and other
1020103
personnel
1020104
(including one person business)
1020105
1020106
1020107
1020108
1020109
1020199
Description
Independent performing artists
(Press, literature)
Translation services
(Press, literature)
Publishing of newspapers
News agency activities
Publishing of magazines and periodicals
Publishing of advertising periodicals
Publishing of textbooks and study books
Publishing of cartoons
Other publishing
Other publishing of prints
(Cards, maps, etc.)
Commercial printing by stencil plates and similar plates or
master printing
(Books, magazines, newspapers, advertising materials)
Screen printing
(Books, magazines, newspapers, advertising materials)
Other printing
(Books, magazines, newspapers, advertising materials)
Printing composition service and plate-making
(Books, magazines, newspapers, advertising materials)
Bookbinding service
(Books, magazines, newspapers, advertising materials)
Other service activities related to printing
(Books, magazines, newspapers, advertising materials)
Wholesale of books, magazines and newspapers
Retail sale of books and magazines
Book renting
Retail sale of stationery
Library and archive activities (Literary books)
Performing arts event promotion and organization
Public performance and production agencies
Other creative and arts-related services n.e.c.
Independent performing artists
(Music, theatrical productions, operas)
Independent non-performing artists
(Music, theatrical productions, operas)
Managers
Ballroom operation
Singing room operation
Recreation education
Other recreation services n.e.c.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
308 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Printing and publishing of music
1020200
Publishing of music and other audio
Production/manufacturing of
recorded music
Wholesale and retail of recorded
music
1020300
Reproduction of musical records and videotapes
1020401
1020402
1020403
1020500
Wholesale of musical records and videotapes
Retail sale of musical records and videotapes
Discs and video tapes renting
Creative and arts support services
1020601
Operation of public performance facilities
(Music, theatrical productions, operas)
Performing arts event promotion and organization
(Music, theatrical productions, operas)
Public performance and production agencies
Other creative and arts-related services n.e.c.
Creative Support Services (art,
literature)
Performances and allied
agencies (bookings, ticket
agencies, etc.)
1020602
1020603
1020699
Motion Picture and Video
Writers, directors, actors
(including one person business)
1030101
1030102
Motion picture and video
production and distribution
1030201
1030202
1030203
1030204
1030205
1030206
Motion picture exhibition
Video rental and sales, video on
demand
Allied services
Radio and television
Television programme production
activities
National radio and television
broadcasting companies
Independent producers
Cable television
Satellite television
Economic Activity (Class)
1030301
1030302
1030401
1030402
1030403
1030500
1040101
1040102
1040103
1040201
1040202
1040203
1040300
1040401
1040402
1040501
1040502
KSCIC
Code
Independent performing artists
(Motion picture, video)
Independent non-performing artists
(Motion picture, video)
General motion picture and video production
Animated cartoon and video production
Commercials advertising motion picture and video
production
Motion picture, video production related services
Motion picture, video distribution
Sound-recording studios
(Motion picture, video)
Motion picture exhibition
Video exhibition rooms
Wholesale of videotapes
Retail sale of videos
Video tape renting
Reproduction of recorded media
(Motion picture, video)
Broadcasting programme production
Broadcasting programmes’ production-related services
Broadcasting programme distribution
Radio broadcasting
Over-the-air broadcasting
Other programme distribution
Broadcasting programme production
(Independent producers)
Wired telecommunications
Cable networks
Satellite telecommunications
Broadcasting via satellite and other broadcasting
Description
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
309 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Photography
Studios and commercial
photography
Photo agencies and libraries
1050101
1050102
1050103
1050104
1050201
1050204
Portrait photography and videotaping of events services
Commercial photography services
Photograph processing
Independent non-performing artists (Photography)
Printing composition services and plate-making
(Photography)
Bookbinding services (Photography)
Other service activities related to printing
(Photography)
Library and archive activities (Photography)
1050299
All other business support services (Photography)
1060101
Online and mobile game software development and supply
1060102
Other game software development and supply
1060103
1060104
1060105
1060106
System software development and supply
Application software development and supply
Computer programming services
Computer system integration consultancy and
establishment services
1060107
1060199
Computer facilities management services
Other information technology and computer operation
related services
1060201
1060202
1060301
1060302
Wholesale of software
Retail sale of software
Data processing
Hosting and related service activities
(database processing)
Portals and other internet information media service
activities
1050202
1050203
Software and databases
Programming, development, and
design manufacturing
Wholesale and retail prepackaged
software
Database processing and
Publishing
1060303
Visual and Graphic arts
Artists(fine arts, crafts, visual
graphics)
Art galleries and other wholesale
and retail
Picture framing and other allied
services
Graphic design
1060304
Database activities and online information provision
services
1070100
1070201
Independent non-performing artists
(Fine arts, crafts, visual graphics)
Arts works and Antiques wholesale and retail
1070202
1070300
Visual arts services (Galleries)
Mounted arts-related services
1070401
1070402
1070403
1070499
Graphic design services
Service activities related to printing(Graphic design)
Editing and proofreading services (Graphic design)
All other business support services (Graphic design)
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
310 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Economic Activity (Class)
Advertising Services
Agencies, buying service
Copyright Collective Societies
Copyright collective societies
KSCIC
Code
Description
1080001
1080002
1080003
1080004
1080005
1080099
Media advertising agencies
Outdoor and exhibition advertising
Media representatives and media buying agencies
Advertising preparation
Market research and public opinion polling
Other advertising n.e.c.
1090001
Professional organizations
(12 copyright collecting societies)
1090002
1090003
Leasing of intangible property rights
Agencies of business and intangible property rights
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
311 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
The United Kingdom
Table A 5.6.
Copyright-intensive
industries Group
Advertising and marketing
Copyright-intensive Industries in the UK (Eurostat)
SIC
Description
70.21
Public relations and communication activities
73.11
Advertising agencies
73.12
Media representation
Architecture
71.11
Architectural activities
Crafts
Design: product, graphic and
fashion design
32.12
Manufacture of jewellery and related articles
74.10
59.11
Specialised design activities
Motion picture, video and television programme production
activities
59.12
Motion picture, video and television programme post-production
59.13
Motion picture, video and television programme distribution
59.14
Motion picture projection activities
60.10
Radio broadcasting
60.20
Television programming and broadcasting activities
74.20
Photographic activities
58.21
Publishing of computer games
58.29
Other software publishing
62.01
Computer programming activities
62.02
Computer consultancy activities
58.11
Book publishing
58.12
Publishing of directories and mailing lists
58.13
Publishing of newspapers
58.14
Publishing of journals and periodicals
58.19
Other publishing activities
74.30
Translation and interpretation activities
91.01
Library and archive activities
91.02
Museum activities
59.20
Sound recording and music publishing activities
85.52
Cultural education
90.01
Performing arts
90.02
Support activities to performing arts
90.03
Artistic creation
90.04
Operation of arts facilities
Film, TV, video, radio and
photography
IT, software and computer
services
Publishing
Museums, galleries and
libraries
Music, performing and visual
arts
Source: The UK Department for Culture, Media and Sport (2014)
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
312 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
The United States
Table A 5.7.
Copyright-intensive Industries in the United States
Type
Industry (NAICS description)
NAICS
code
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Newspaper, periodical, book, and directory publishers
5111
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Software publishers
5112
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Motion picture and video industries
5121
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Sound recording industries
5122
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Radio and television broadcasting
5151
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Cable and other subscription programming
5152
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Specialized design services (visual and graphic arts)
5414
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Computer systems
databases)
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Advertising, public relations, and related services
5418
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Other professional, scientific, and technical services (photography and
translation)
5419
Core (ESA-USPTO and Siwek-IIPA)
Performing arts companies
7111
Core (ESA-USPTO)
Independent artists, writers, and performers
7115
Core (ESA-USPTO)
Other information services (news syndicates and internet sites)
5191
Core (Siwek-IIPA)
Printing and related support activities
3231
Core (Siwek-IIPA)
Manufacturing and reproducing magnetic and optical media
3346
design
and
related
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
services
(software
and
5415
313 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
NOTES
150
As noted, this study is based on an examination of 12 jurisdictions. The economic trends and legal debates
that are developed therefore may not reflect those of every Member State of the OECD. In particular, the
analyses and conclusions from this Chapter, and their summary in Chapter 1, may not be applicable in the
OECD countries which did not participate in the study.
151
Directive on the harmonisation of certain aspects of copyright and related rights in the information society
(2001/29/EC).
152
Orphan works have been referred to as copyrighted works whose rights holder cannot be identified and/or
located.
153
WIPO Copyright Treaty, adopted in Geneva on December 20, 1996; and WIPO Performances and
Phonograms Treaty, adopted in Geneva on December 20, 1996; available at http://www.wipo.int/treaties.
154
See BSA (2014), Danaher et al. (2012), Juniper Research (2104).
155
For example, according to a recent report by KPMG, 86% of most popular film and TV titles in the UK are
available via legitimate services (KPMG, 2014). See also BSA (2014), Danaher et al. (2012), Juniper
Research (2104).
156
Source: https://www.flickr.com/photos/franckmichel/6855169886/
157
Copyrights are be limited by certain limitations and exceptions. This issue is presented in Sections one and
three of this chapter.
158
These include: Berne Convention for the Protection of Literary and Artistic Works (of September 9, 1886,
completed at Paris on May 4, 1896, and revised and amended several time since then; last amendment in
September 28. 1979); International Convention for the Protection of Performers, Producers of Phonograms
and Broadcasting Organizations (Rome Convention; done at Rome on October 26, 1961); Convention for
the Protection of Producers of Phonograms against Unauthorized Duplication of their Phonograms (of
October 29, 1971); Copyright Treaty (adopted in Geneva on December 20, 1996); Beijing Treaty on
Audiovisual Performances (adopted by the Diplomatic Conference on the Protection of Audiovisual
Performances in Beijing, on June 24, 2012); Marrakesh Treaty to Facilitate Access to Published Works for
Persons Who Are Blind, Visually Impaired or Otherwise Print Disabled (adopted by the Diplomatic
Conference to Conclude a Treaty to Facilitate Access to Published Works by Visually Impaired Persons
and Persons with Print Disabilities in Marrakesh, on June 27, 2013).
159
Article 5(2) of Berne conventions states that “[t]he enjoyment and the exercise of [copyrights] shall not be
subject to any formality.”
160
While this chapter focuses primarily on the copyright intensive industries, it is also important to
acknowledge the expanding body of user generated digital content. The Internet and hardware from
cameras to smart phones empower individuals to create and disseminate digital content which is now
another important source of information and entertainment.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
314 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
161
Source: https://www.flickr.com/photos/franckmichel/6855169886/
162
Source: http://mashable.com/2013/09/16/facebook-photo-uploads/
163
Source: http://instagram.com/press/
164
Source :
http://www.apple.com/pr/library/2013/02/06iTunes-Store-Sets-New-Record-with-25-BillionSongs-Sold.html
165
Source : http://press.spotify.com/fr/information/
166
Source: https://www.youtube.com/yt/press/statistics.html
167
Source: OECD based on Instantwatcher (http://instantwatcher.com/titles/all)
168
The comprehensive database of services is searchable by country, language, genre and other factors and
can be found at http://mavise.obs.coe.int/welcome
169
The growth in new business models may not offset the initial drop in sales.
170
See page endnote 5.
171
For more information see the final report of High Level Expert Group on Digital Libraries advising the
European Commission in the framework of the i2010 Digital Libraries Initiative. Available at:
http://www.dlorg.eu/uploads/External%20Publications/HLG%20Final%20Report%202009%20clean.pdf
172
For a detailed list of copyright-intensive industries in Australia, see table A 5.1 in the Annex.
173
More detailed info can be found in the document "Short guide to copyright". Available at:
http://www.ag.gov.au/RightsAndProtections/IntellectualProperty/Pages/Copyright-information.aspx
174
See “Australian Copyright Council Information sheet G101v04”. Available at:
http://www.copyright.org.au/admin/cms-acc1/_images/1549612446523924db2ad24.pdf
175
See: http://www.alrc.gov.au/publications/copyright-report-122
176
See Figure 5.3.16 of the Communications Monitoring Report 2014: Telecommunications Sector by the
Canadian Radio-television and Telecommunications Commission. Available at:
http://www.crtc.gc.ca/eng/publications/reports/PolicyMonitoring/2014/cmr5.htm#s5-3i
177
For a detailed list of copyright-intensive industries in Canada, see table A 5.2 in the Annex.
178
Statistics Canada (2013), Report titled: “Digital Technology and Internet Use, 2012”, available at:
http://www.statcan.gc.ca/daily-quotidien/130612/dq130612a-eng.pdf
179
Statistics Canada (2011), Sound Recording and Music
http://www.statcan.gc.ca/pub/87f0008x/87f0008x2013001-eng.pdf
180
Entertainment Software Association of Canada (2013), Canada’s Video Game Industry in 2013, Final
Report, available at: http://theesa.ca/wp-content/uploads/2013/10/ESAC-Video-Games-Profile-2013FINAL-2013-10-21-CIRC.pdf
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
Publishing,
available
at:
315 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
181
Book Net Canada (2013), The State of Digital Publishing in Canada 2013, available at:
http://www.booknetcanada.ca/storage/research-education/state-of-digitalpublishing/BNC_Research_TheStateofDigitalPublishinginCanada_2013.pdf
182
See: http://www.ic.gc.ca/eic/site/crp-prda.nsf/eng/rp00863.html
183
The summary can be found at: http://copyright.econsultation.ca/
184
For a detailed list, see Annex 4 of the following document:
http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/copyright/en/performance/pdf/econ_contribution_cr_ca.pdf
185
More detailed info can be found at: http://www.egov.ufsc.br/portal/sites/default/files/7_0.pdf
186
For more information see:
http://www.propiedadintelectual.cl/Vistas_Publicas/publicContenido/contenidoPublicDetalle.asp
x?folio=4183&idioma=0 (in Spanish). The relevant provisions are in articles 71A to 71S.
187
See:
www.propiedadintelectual.cl/Vistas_Publicas/publicNoticias/noticiasPublicDetalle.aspx?idNoticia=43733
188
See: www.inapi.cl/protegetuidea/
189
Harabi, N. (2004), Creative Industries: Case Studies from Arab Countries, Munich Personal RePEc
Archive Paper No. 15628, Available at: http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/15628/; WIPO (2003),
Performance
of
Copyright
Industries
in
Selected
Arab
Countries,
Available
at:
http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/freepublications/en/copyright/916/wipo_pub_916.pdf
190
UNCTAD Secretariat Calculation based on United Nations Comtrade database data and IMF Balance of
Payments Statistics and UNCTAD Calculation based on IMF Balance of Payments Statistics.
191
UNESCO's Arabic Language Day press release.Available at:
http://www.unesco.org/new/en/media-services/single-view/news/world_arabic_language_day/
192
For detailed list of copyright-intensive industries in the EU see table A 5.3 in the Annex.
193
Article 5; Directive 2001/29/EC.
194
Directive 2001/29/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 22 May 2001 on the harmonisation
of certain aspects of copyright and related rights in the information society
195
See: http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/copyright/docs/copyright-infso/greenpaper_en.pdf
196
See: http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/consultations/2013/copyrightrules/docs/contributions/consultation-report_en.pdf
197
For a detailed list of copyright-intensive industries in Italy, see table A 5.3 in the Annex.
198
For further information see AGCOM, https://www.ddaonline.it/
199
In particular, CRTV, IMAE, Motion Picture Licensing Corporation Italy, SCF, IPAA and FAPAV are not
associated in “Confindustria Cultura Italia”.
200
This annex is based on Confindustria Radio Televisioni [CRTV], (2014).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
316 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
201
Additional information on legal online offer in Italy (eBook, film, music, B2b, TV, videogames) is
available on www.mappadeicontenuti.it.
202
For a detailed list of copyright-intensive industries in Japan, see table A 5.4 in the Annex.
203
See: eMarketer, Global B2C Ecommerce Sales to Hit $1.5 Trillion This Year Driven by Growth in
Emerging Markets; available at: http://www.emarketer.com/Article/Global-B2C-Ecommerce-Sales-Hit-15Trillion-This-Year-Driven-by-Growth-Emerging-Markets/1010575 and eMarketer, B2C Ecommerce
Climbs Worldwide, as Emerging Markets Drive Sales Higher available at:
http://www.emarketer.com/Article/B2C-Ecommerce-Climbs-Worldwide-Emerging-Markets-Drive-SalesHigher/1010004
204
See ComScore, 2010 Mobile Year in Review; available at:
http://www.comscore.com/Insights/Presentations_and_Whitepapers/2011/2010_Mobile_Year_in_Review .
205
See http://www.cric.or.jp/english/csj/csj2.html.
206
See http://www.cric.or.jp/english/qa/begin.html
207
See: http://www.cric.or.jp/english/qa/begin.html#9
208
Original name: 文化審議会著作権分科会
209
See: http://www.bunka.go.jp/chosakuken/singikai/index.html (Japanese only).
210
Japan Copyright Institute (2009), Copyright White Paper - A view from the perspective of copyright
industries (vol.3), Japan Copyright Institute, Copyright Research and Information Center, August 2009;
available at: http://www.cric.or.jp/english/doc/whitepaper_0908.pdf
211
For a more exhaustive list see: http://www.cric.or.jp/english/csj/csj7.html
212
For a detailed list of copyright-intensive industries in Korea, see table A 5.5 in the Annex.
213
See endnote 1.
214
See the part on enforcement.
215
Article 101ter deals with limitations and exceptions only with respect to computer programs.
216
This act has been revised several times in compliance with the TRIPS Agreement and the free trade
agreements between Korea and the European Union (2011) and between Korea the United States (2012).
217
For a detailed list of copyright-intensive industries in Poland, see table A 5.3 in the Annex.
218
http://www.muzo.pl
219
http://muzodajnia.pl
220
http://iplay.pl
221
http://www.empik.com
222
http://www.soho.pl
223
http://www.polishsound.com
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
317 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
224
http://nuplays.pl
225
http://www.mobila.pl
226
http://www.papla.pl
227
http://www.playthemusic.pl
228
http://www.mood.pl
229
http://www.windmobile.pl
230
http://soundpark.pl
231
http://www.megatotal.pl
232
http://www.megatunes.pl
233
See “Report on the functioning of the digital music market in Poland 2013”; available at: .
http://www.prawoautorskie.gov.pl/media/raporty/Report_on_the_functioning_of_the_digital_music_marke
t_in_Poland_2013.pdf
234
Source - http://www.zpav.pl/aktualnosci.php?idaktualnosci=862
235
Ustawa z dnia 4 lutego 1994 r. o prawie autorskim i prawach pokrewnych.
236
Ustawa z dnia 27 lipca 2001 r. o ochronie baz danych.
237
www.prawoautorskie.gov.pl
238
See http://www.eschk.admin.ch/eschk/de/home.html
239
More information can be found at: https://www.ige.ch/urheberrecht/agur12.html
240
For a detailed list of copyright-intensive industries in the United Kingdom, see table A 5.6 in the Annex.
241
See: https://www.gov.uk/apply-for-a-licence-to-use-an-orphan-work
242
For points raised
policy/consult.htm
243
The UK’s position is set out at http://www.ipo.gov.uk/response-eucopyrightrules.pdf
244
More information on the implementation of the report’s recommendations in the area of copyright can be
found here: http://www.ipo.gov.uk/types/hargreaves/hargreaves-copyright.htm
245
For a detailed list see: http://www.ipo.gov.uk/types/copy/c-manage/c-ownerorg.htm
246
For a detailed list of copyright-intensive industries in the United States, see table A 5.7 in the Annex.
247
See ESA-USPTO (2010); Siwek-IIPA (2004).
248
Copyright Act of 1976, Pub. L. No. 94-553, 90 Stat. 2541 (1976). For a listing of amendments made
subsequent to the passage of the 1976 Act see Copyright Office Circular 92 at:
http://www.copyright.gov/title17/circ92.pdf.
in
public
consultations
around
copyright
see
http://www.ipo.gov.uk/pro-
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
318 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
249
For more information on the history of copyright revision in the United States in the context of the Internet
revolution, see the Preface to Title 17, available at: http://www.copyright.gov/title17/92preface.html.
See also Section II.B of the Department of Commerce Green Paper. on Copyright Policy, Creativity, and
Innovation in the Digital Economy (“Green Paper), available at:
http://www.uspto.gov/news/publications/copyrightgreenpaper.pdf
250
Pub. L. No. 105-304, 112 Stat. 2860 (1998). For a summary of the law passed in 1998, see the
US Copyright Office Summary of the legislation available at:
http://www.copyright.gov/legislation/dmca.pdf
251
17 U.S.C. §§ 302-305. Some of the more common circumstances are described in Copyright Office
Circular 15a. And works made for hire under the 1976 Act are described in Circular 9. All Copyright
Office Circulars are available at http://www.copyright.gov/circs/
252
17 U.S.C. § 701 (a).
253
17 U.S.C. § 701 (b).
254
17 U.S.C. §§ 101 (definition of “compilation”) & 103. For more information see:
http://www.copyright.gov/reports/dbase.html
255
17 U.S.C. §107. See also U.S. Copyright Fact Sheet FL-102, available at:
http://www.copyright.gov/fls/fl102.html
256
More information on the Copyright Office’s docket on orphan works and mass digitization can be found at
http://www.copyright.gov/orphan. Additional background from the perspective of the U.S. Department of
Commerce can be found in the Green Paper (pp 30-33).
257
See Circular 1, available at http://www.copyright.gov/circs/circ01.pdf, at page 7.
258
U.S. Department of Justice, Fourth Edition of the Department of Justice’s Manual on Prosecuting IP
Crimes, issued in 2013, available at
http://www.justice.gov/criminal/cybercrime/docs/prosecuting_ip_crimes_manual_2013.pdf.
259
Maria A. Pallante, The Next Great Copyright Act, 2013 Manges Lecture at Columbia Law School,
http://www.copyright.gov/docs/next_great_copyright_act.pdf.
260
To find more information on these and future hearings, see United States House of Representatives
Judiciary Committee, Hearings, available at: http://judiciary.house.gov/index.cfm/hearings.
261
See USCO webpage on this study, including a link to the final report, available at:
http://www.copyright.gov/docs/smallclaims/
262
See USCO webpage on this study, including a link to the final report, available at:
http://www.copyright.gov/docs/resaleroyalty/
263
See USCO webpage on the right of making available study, available at:
http://www.copyright.gov/docs/making_available/
264
See USCO webpage on the music licensing study, available at:
http://www.copyright.gov/docs/musiclicensingstudy/
265
Links to all these ongoing efforts of the Copyright Office can be accessed on its homepage:
www.copyright.gov.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
319 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
266
Available at: www.uspto.gov/news/publications/copyrightgreenpaper.pdf
267
Green Paper at p. iii.
268
A discussion of private action and available remedies in the area of enforcement of copyrights can be found
in the Green Paper (section III B 2).
269
http://www.copyrightinformation.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/05/Phase-One-And_Beyond.pdf
270
A discussion of private action and available remedies in the area of enforcement of copyrights can be found
in the Green Paper (section III B 2).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
320 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
REFERENCES
Business Software Alliance [BSA] (2014), "BSA Global Software Survey 2013", Available at:
http://globalstudy.bsa.org/2013/downloads/studies/2013GlobalSurvey_Study_en.pdf
Confindustria Radio Televisioni [CRT] (2014), “Analisi e dati”, presented on 3rd July 2014, at the 9th
Committee on Transportation, Post and Telecommunications of the Chamber of Deputies [IX
Commissione Trasporti, Poste e Telecomunicazioni] available at: http://www.confindustriaradiotv.it/wpcontent/uploads/2014/07/INDAGINE-CONOSCITIVA-IX-COMMISSIONE-CAMERA_-3luglio_dati.pdf
Danaher, B., S. Dhanasobhon, M. D. Smith, and R. Telang (2010): “Converting Pirates Without
Cannibalizing Purchasers: The Impact of Digital Distribution on Physical Sales and Internet Piracy,”
Marketing Science, 29, 1138–1151
Das, S., A. Mukhopadhyay and K. K. Bagchi (2014), National-Level Determinants of Global Music
Piracy and Online Music Sales: An Exploratory Study, Journal of Global Information Technology
Management, Vol. 17(1)
DeCarlo, M. (2012), “Gartner: SSDs will reach mainstream prices in 2012”, TechSpot, 11 May,
available at www.techspot.com/news/43752-gartner-ssds-will-reach-mainstream-prices-in-2012.html
Enders,
A.
(2013),
LGC2:
Progress
towards
Digital
Europe,
available
http://www.letsgoconnected.eu/files/LGC2_Progress_towards_Digital_Europe_FINAL.pdf
at:
Economics and Statistics Administration and the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office [ESA-USPTO]
(2012), Intellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: An Industry Focus, available at:
http://www.uspto.gov/news/publications/IP_Report_March_2012.pdf
EPO-OHIM (2013), Intellectual property rights intensive industries: contribution to economic
performance and employment in the European Union. Industry-Level Analysis Report, September 2013;
available at: http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/intellectual-property/docs/joint-report-epo-ohim-finalversion_en.pdf
Gantchev, D. (2004), The WIPO Guide on Surveying the Economic Contribution of the Copyright
Industries. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 5-15
Economics and Statistics Administration and the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office [ESA-USPTO]
(2012), Intellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: An Industry Focus, available at:
http://www.uspto.gov/news/publications/IP_Report_March_2012.pdf
Greenhalgh, Ch. and M. Rogers (2010), Innovation, Intellectual Property, and Economic Growth,
Princeton University Press
Handke, Christian, A Taxonomy of Empirical Research on Copyright - How Do We Inform Policy?
(July 5, 2012). Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 2012, 9(1), 47-92. Available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2101084
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
321 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
Hargreaves, I. (2011), Digital Opportunity. A review of Intellectual Property and Growth. An
independent report by Ian Hargreaves. Available at: http://www.ipo.gov.uk/ipreview-finalreport.pdf
Hegazy, M. A., and Gadallah, Y. M. (2013): National Study for IP and Micro, Small- and Mediumsized Enterprises in Egypt, Prepared for WIPO SME Division, Cairo and Geneva: Information Technology
Industry Development Agency (ITIDA) and WIPO.
Iglesias, M. (2009) “Digital libraries and silent works”, in ed. Casanovas Sartor et al., Law and
Technology: Looking into the Future Selected Essays, European Press Academic Publishing
International Federation of the Phonographic Industry [IFPI] (2013), IFPI Digital Music Report 2013;
Available at: http://www.ifpi.org/downloads/dmr2013-full-report_english.pdf
Japan Copyright Institute (2009), Copyright White Paper - A view from the perspective of copyright
industries (vol.3), Japan Copyright Institute, Copyright Research and Information Center, August 2009;
available at: http://www.cric.or.jp/english/doc/whitepaper_0908.pdf
Jockers, M. L., Sag, M., & Schultz, J. (2012). Digital archives: Don't let copyright block data mining.
Nature, 490(7418), 29-30.
Juniper Research (2014), Digital Music: Streaming, Download & Legacy Services 2014–2019.
Available at: http://www.juniperresearch.com/whitepaper/music
KEA (2011) Audiovisual Orphan Works in Europe – national survey. Report prepared for the British
Film
Institute
(BFI).
Available
at:
http://www.keanet.eu/docs/ORPHAN%20WORKS%20STUDY%20KEA.pdf
KPGM (2014), UK Availability of Film and TV Titles in the Digital Age. Available at:
http://www.kpmg.com/UK/en/IssuesAndInsights/ArticlesPublications/Documents/PDF/Market%20Sector/
Technology/uk-availability-of-film-andtv.pdf?utm_medium=social&utm_source=twitter&utm_campaign=nbc
Kranenburg, H.L. van and Hogenbirk, A.E. (2003), Determinants of multimedia, entertainment, and
business software copyright piracy: a cross-national study, METEOR Research Memorandum 020.
Maastricht: METEOR, Maastricht University School of Business and Economics
Kretschmer, T. (2012), “Information and Communication Technologies and Productivity Growth: A
Survey of the Literature”, OECD Digital Economy Papers, No. 195] and [OECD (2013), "Measuring the
Internet Economy: A Contribution to the Research Agenda", OECD Digital Economy Papers, No. 226,
OECD Publishing
Landes, W.M. and R. A. Posner (1989), An Economic Analysis of Copyright Law. Journal of Legal
Studies 325, 325-33, 344-53 (1989)
Let’s Go Connected (2013), Intellectual Property and the Creative Economy, A White paper by Let's
Go
Connected,
Special
Edition
WIPO
2013,
Available
at:
http://www.letsgoconnected.eu/files/Lets_go_connected-09-2013.pdf
McDonald, D., McNicoll, I., Weir, G., Reimer, T., Redfearn, J., Jacobs, N., and Bruce, R. (2012). The
value and benefits of text mining. JISC Digital Infrastructure
Netanel, N. (2008), Copyright’s paradox. Oxford University Press
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
322 | COPYRIGHT IN THE DIGITAL ERA: COUNTRY STUDIES
NPD
Group
(2013),
Online
Gaming
2013,
Press
release
available
https://www.npd.com/wps/portal/npd/us/news/press-releases/the-npd-group-report-shows-increasednumber-of-online-gamers-and-hours-spent-gaming/
OECD (2008), The Seoul Declaration
Available at: www.oecd.org/sti/40839436.pdf
for
the
Future
of
the
Internet
at:
Economy,
OECD (2011), OECD Council Recommendation on Principles for Internet Policy Making, Available
at: www.oecd.org/internet/ieconomy/49258588.pdf
OECD (2012a), OECD Internet Economy Outlook 2012, OECD Publishing
OECD (2012b), "E-books: Developments and Policy Considerations", OECD Digital Economy
Papers No. 208, OECD Publishing.
OECD (2013a), OECD Communications Outlook 2013, OECD Publishing
OECD (2013b), "Exploring Data-Driven Innovation as a New Source of Growth: Mapping the Policy
Issues Raised by "Big Data"", OECD Digital Economy Papers, No. 222, OECD Publishing
OECD (2014), “Consumer Policy Guidance on Intangible Digital Content Products”, OECD Digital
Economy Papers, No. 241, OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jxvbrjq3gg6-en
Pingdom, R. (2011), “Would you pay $7,260 for a 3 TB drive? Charting HDD and SSD prices over
time”, 19
December, http://royal.pingdom.com/2011/12/19/would-you-pay-7260-for-a-3-tb-drivechartinghdd-and-ssd-prices-over-time
Png, I. P. (2006), Copyright: A plea for empirical research. Review of Economic Research on
Copyright Issues, 3(2)
Raustiala, K. and Ch. J. Sprigman (2006), The Piracy Paradox: Innovation and Intellectual Property in
Fashion Design. Virginia Law Review, 92, Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=878401piracy
Siwek, S. E., prepared for the International Intellectual Property Alliance [Siwek-IIPA] (2013),
Copyright
Industries
in
the
U.S.
Economy:
The
2013
Report,
available
at:
http://www.iipa.com/pdf/2013_Copyright_Industries_Full_Report.PDF
Thorpe, J. (2004), Some Challenges for Copyright-Related Quantification. Review of Economic
Research on Copyright Issues, Vol. 1(1). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1146193
The Office of the US Trade Representative [USTR] (2014), 2014 Special 301 Report
The UK Department for Culture, Media and Sport (2014) Creative Industries Economic Estimates January 2014, available at: https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/creative-industries-economicestimates-january-2014
Watt, R. (2004), The Past and the Future of the Economics of Copyright. Review of Economic
Research on Copyright Issues, Vol. 1(1). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1143022
World Intellectual Property Organization [WIPO] (2003), Guide on Surveying the Economic
Contribution of the Copyright-Based Industries, WIPO Publication No. 893(E), available at:
http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/copyright/en/performance/pdf/econ_contribution_cr_us.pdf.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
323 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
CHAPTER 6. DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND
ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
This chapter addresses the nature and the economic impact of design by looking at design-related
intellectual property and how businesses protect their knowledge based capital.
The chapter reviews the nature and various definitions of design and how design-related IP, specifically
registered designs, relates to other formal IP mechanisms such as patents, trademarks, and copyright. It
looks at the primary areas of design activity in a subset of OECD countries and investigates the similarities
and differences of the constituent design IP regimes as well as the various treaties governing international
design IP regulation. The review continues with an examination of how design-related IP functions in
comparison to and in conjunction with other formal and informal IP protection mechanisms and what
factors motivate firms to choose and appropriate combinations of protection mechanisms.
By examining historical patterns of design registrations in a variety of ways, this chapter identifies trends,
at the national level, of how firms perceive the importance of design-related IP. Analysis of national
origins of registrations in both the European Community and the United States provides an indicator of the
activity of those countries’ businesses relative to their proximities to the markets. It explores the existence
of possible alternative indicators for design activity and of industry-specific variations across the sample
set.
The chapter concludes with a review of input and output measures as stated in the limited set of studies that
have endeavoured to establish or quantify the value and/or benefit of design and design-related IP. The
studies, while clearly suggesting that design does have economic benefits, both at the firm and overall
economic levels, largely use qualitative or subjective indicators because the data necessary for large-scale
econometric analysis are generally not available.
This chapter is intended to be exploratory rather than comprehensive or conclusive. It should be considered
as an initial step towards the possibility of a broader and deeper analysis of design-related issues.
The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities or third
party. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and
Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.
It should be noted that statistical data on Israeli patents and trademarks are supplied by the patent and trademark
offices of the relevant countries.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
324 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Introduction
Design is the essence of all non-commoditised products—not only does it provide a means for
differentiating products and services, but it also dictates the core user experience with those products and
services. It goes beyond the pure aesthetics that we normally envision as the key to design, and
encompasses features including the functionality and ergonomics behind every product. To that end, what
is design? Where does technological development end and design begin? If there is no clear terminator,
how do we quantify what is invention and what is design?
While these questions, among others, have occupied researchers and managers alike, few answers are
apparent. As Afori so aptly put it, “A design is hard to define but is easily described.” (2008, p. 1107). This
reflects how automatically we view all the aspects of design; to the extent that we do not cognitively
process them, so much as we simply experience them. Likewise, managers often overlook some aspects of
design, and it is difficult to identify—let alone measure—all the elements of design inputs in a product. Is
developing a better user interface a matter of engineering or design? Are engineers designers and vice
versa?
Through the advent of the patent system, we tend to identify inventions as discrete packets, and while
there are also means of codifying design elements, it is rare that all elements of design are equally as well
defined and protected. Thus, there is that much less substance by which to measure design (Black and
Baker, 1987, Hertenstein et al., 2005). Nonetheless, there is general recognition about design being a major
contributor to the economic fortunes of companies and to the regional and national economies to which
they belong (Hertenstein et al., 2005, Kotler and Rath, 1984, Walsh et al., 1992, Yamamoto and Lambert,
1994).
In this document, we explore the nature of design, with a focus on industrial design, and examine how
firms protect their design-related intellectual property and how, if at all, that has changed over the last ten
years. We review what measures there are for design inputs and outputs, and suggest future directions for
evaluating the benefits of design to firms and economies.
Defining design and industrial design
Design was once perceived as a mere decorative craft; however, it has since been recognised as the
intersection between technology and the user. Firms previously left the product to be defined by its
function and thus produced goods that functioned well in reference to their defined purpose but made
fewer allowances for how the user would interact with it. Design has since become a study of ergonomics,
consumer psychology, sociology, human dynamics, art, and software engineering as well as service and
technology innovation (Buchanan and Margolin, 1995). A large part of the literature acknowledges design
as an important competitive tool, as well as an intangible factor that contributes in most cases to the valueadded and success of companies.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
325 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Box 6.1.
What exactly is design?
The word design is widely used and can mean different things. Everything that surrounds us can claim to be the
work of design: from buildings to cars, from furniture to product packaging. Walsh (1996) claims “the term ‘design’
covers a wide range of activities: architecture, fashion design, interior design, graphic design, industrial design,
engineering design.” Nevertheless, the difficulty remains that design has been defined in many ways but no single
definition has been universally accepted (Gemser and Leenders, 2001).
While they are generally similar in nature, the definitions of design used for legislative and/or regulatory purposes
differ somewhat:
•
EU Council: “Design means the appearance of the whole or a part of a product resulting from the features of,
in particular, the lines, contours, colours, shape, texture and/or materials of the product itself and/or its
ornamentation.” (European Commission, 2002)
•
OHIM: “Design is an art and a science, it forms our homes and our workplace, and it is all around us,
wherever we are. Design is the surface of the man-made environment.” (OHIM, 2013a)
•
WIPO: “An industrial design constitutes the ornamental or aesthetic aspect of an article. A design may consist
of three-dimensional features, such as the shape or surface of an article, or of two-dimensional features, such
as patterns, lines or colour.” (WIPO, 2014b)
Scholars also provide a set of definitions that give different facets to design according to the dimension and the
context in which it is placed.
As suggested by D'Ippolito (2014), the nature of how we think about and study design has evolved over the years
through several different philosophies:
•
Design as creation of artefacts— Consisting of “studying, researching, and investigating the artificial made
by human beings and the way these activities have been explored in academia or employed in
manufacturing.” (D'Ippolito, 2014, p. 29, Simon, 1969)
•
Design as a problem-solving activity—A process involving problem definition, solution generation,
evaluation, and selection.
•
Design as a reflexive practice and design as making sense of things— The designer not only creates but
also reflects upon the creation so as to learn, improve, and re-create (D'Ippolito, 2014, p. 29, JohanssonSköldberg et al., 2013).
•
Design as a key input to strategy— is conceived as the means to increase the competitiveness of firms:
“Design relates directly to the strategy of the firm. It seeks to optimise consumer satisfaction and company
profitability through the creation of form, durability and values along with products environments, information,
and identities.” (D'Ippolito, 2014, p. 29, Kotler and Rath, 1984)
Design protections
Industrial design refers to creative activity that results in the ornamental or formal appearance of a
product (Sharma et al., 2011). This appearance may include the “look and feel” of a product, and can
extend to the on-screen depiction of a website. For the purpose of this document, the nature of design is
entirely separate from function or technical merits. That is to say, that any inherent aspect of a design that
has functional significance may be excluded from design protections. However, what happens when the
design is functional? Consider the case of a company that makes automobile tyres; if it uses the same
materials, the same construction, and the same technology for a new tyre design as it does for its other
tyres—and for that matter, as its competitors use, as well—what sets its products apart? The tread design is
a pattern with a unique outward appearance that differentiates it from other designs and products; however,
the new tread design, while not necessarily using novel elements, may contribute significantly to the tyre’s
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
326 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
ability to disperse water and adhere better to the road surface (Scalera et al., 2014). This may or may not
bring design into “conflict” with patents, as patents must, as a basic requirement, have utility (i.e. function)
unless the cognisant jurisdiction allows design patents. For example, In the United States, an article of
manufacture (such as a tyre) may have both a utility patent (how it functions) and a design patent (how it
looks). In the U.S., both design and utility patents may be obtained on an article if invention resides both in
its utility and ornamental appearance. While utility and design patents afford legally separate protection,
the utility and ornamentality of an article are not easily separable.
The aesthetic aspects that distinguish a product from others represent an opportunity for the producer,
as product design gives an image and reputation to the company, and contributes to increase the firms’
competitiveness and performance. For this reason, it becomes essential for enterprises to protect their
design assets against copying by competitors and counterfeiters. However, some protections are similarly
afforded under copyright and trademark protection (Brean, 2008). Copyright protects various artistic and
software works, while trademark allows firms to indefinitely protect iconic elements that serve as
representations that link firms with their brand and products (Jackson, 2014).
The protection of industrial design is a debated issue due to these conflicts regarding scope of
protection and methods of enforcement (Lahore, 1971, Copinger and James, 1999). The reason is that “the
industrial design is situated at the crossroads of art, technology, and the entire industry dedicated to
attracting the consumer’s attention. Legally speaking, design suffers from a hybrid nature since it has much
in common with the three major intellectual property paradigms – copyright, patent and trademark laws—
yet it does not exactly fit any one of them.” (Afori, 2008, pp. 1107-1108) In the U.S., both design and
utility patents may be obtained on an article if invention resides both in its utility and ornamental
appearance.
The role of design: Product design and the design process
Design is a method whereby firms can add value to their products and services and differentiate
themselves from their competitors (Rothwell and Gardiner, 1985). By bridging the gap between
technological function and user experience, some argue that design spurs innovation (Kline and Rosenberg,
1986, Rothwell, 1992, Walsh, 1996). Since it is concerned with the outward—or “customer facing”—part
of the product, design can be considered the most direct and impactful medium through which firms can
communicate with customers (Verganti, 2003).
Given that it is difficult to assign a single clear definition of design since the term applies to a wide
range of activities that can be at the one extreme “engineering” and at the other “art” (Lawson, 2006), it
becomes even more difficult to categorise or measure design. As mentioned above, the role of design is
often associated mainly with aesthetic aspects of the product, and sometimes, but not always, considered a
key aspect of the product development process. Whereas some people consider design to be an activity,
others think of it as a process and still others treat it as a philosophy (Krippendorff, 1989).
Design can be viewed as a communicator of the firm’s quality image and product integrity
(Yamamoto and Lambert, 1994), but design can have a variety of functions that vary from firm to firm or
from process to process within the same firm. Perks et al. (2005) explores the role of design within the
new product development (NPD) process and identifies three potential roles design can play:
1. Design as a functional specialism: in this category, designers concentrate mainly on design and
with the aesthetic aspects of NPD;
2. Design as part of multifunctional team: here a team approach is used and the designers emerge as
key players participating in NPD-related decision making along with other experts; and
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
327 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
3. Design as NPD process leader and a major force for innovation: the designer is the leader of the
NPD process who drives and supports actions throughout it.
This is similar to Kotler and Rath (1984), who define design as “a strategic marketing tool” that seeks
to optimise consumer satisfaction and company profitability. They propose three different “Design
philosophies” to explain how companies incorporate design into the marketing planning process, from
design-dominated companies, in which designers create without any marketing data to market-dominated
companies, in which designers have to adhere closely to market research reports describing what customers
want in the product.
Figure 6.1.
Conceptualisation of design
Source: Moultrie and Livesey 2014
The design role is not even necessarily limited to new products and services: it could deal with other
aspects of the business, such as communication and branding activities (Walsh, 1996). The British
Standard guide to managing design (2005) draws a distinction between two aspects of design: the first
concerns promotion and customer support that includes many elements such as advertising, packaging,
promotional literature, etc. This is a design that communicates, promotes, and delivers products and
services; the second concerns creation, communication and promotion of corporate identity and culture,
therefore design reflects the “personality” of the organisation.
The Fourth Community Innovation Survey (CIS-4) considers design’s role as a part of marketing
innovation; Filippetti (2011), in fact, references the CIS-4 clarification on design, “a marketing innovation
is the implementation of new and significantly improved design and sales methods to increase the appeal
of your goods and services or to enter to new markets.” (p. 9) In this case, design is considered as an
output and not as a process or source of innovation, because, as mentioned by the OECD (2005),
“marketing innovations include significant changes in product design that are a part of a new marketing
concept. Product design changes here refer to changes in product form and appearance that do not alter the
product’s functional or user characteristics” (p. 49); but, in general, there seems to be a semantic confusion
as to whether design is a process or an outcome (Bloch, 2011).
Design can play different roles within companies depending on the type of enterprise, and the
importance that management chooses to assign to it. This will depend on the individual company's
philosophy and the sector in which it operates, whether to limit design to the product or extend it to a
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
328 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
whole process. By integrating design into the entire process at an earlier stage of new product
development, firms have been able to attain efficiencies, in both time and cost (Gemser and Leenders,
2001). Therefore, it often becomes complex to recognise and measure the weight and role that design plays
in different firms. We will explore these issues further in the next sections of this report. Section 2
presents design protection regimes in the sample countries we will emphasise, Section 3 discusses IPrelated issues, Section 4 explores trends in registered designs, while Sections 5 and 6 talk about measures
of inputs and outputs, respectively.
Protecting design
Many industries are making significant changes in how they invest in and protect their design-related
intellectual property. This section of the report will deal with the regimes of design IP in a sample of
countries: Canada, France, Germany, United Kingdom, Italy, Japan, United States, South Korea, and
China.
Design IP v. patents, trademarks and copyrights: Subset or complement?
It is important to differentiate design as a form of intellectual property, possibly distinct from other
forms of intellectual property such as patents, copyrights and trademarks.
Various nations and governing bodies use different terms for design intellectual property: Registered
design, registered community design, design model, design patent, industrial design, etc. For the purposes
of this document, we will use registered design for the intellectual property right and design or industrial
design to refer to the larger concept of design as an activity, practice, or element of bringing aesthetic or
visual change to an otherwise commoditised product.
The registration of inventions having functional or technological utility beyond or without regard to
aesthetics also has a number of mechanisms. These mechanisms—which are referred to under a number of
designations such as patent, utility patent, petty patent, innovation patent, small patent, and utility model—
will be largely treated in this report as patents unless otherwise stipulated.
For the purpose of this report, we will use the term trademark (as opposed to trade mark or trademark) to represent the visual elements that link an enterprise with its products and services. This can be
indicative of both registered and unregistered trademarks; however, the general discussion will be
concerned with registered IPRs.
Registered designs
Registered designs are granted by different jurisdictions as a form of formal intellectual property
protecting ornamental properties, shapes, configurations, appearance, or pattern of an article of
manufacture, and such designs must be both new and distinctive or original. Registered designs have
different names in different countries or regions, including “community designs” or “design patents.” In
the interest of consistency, we will use the term registered design in this report 271.
Different jurisdictions have different defined periods of time that registered designs may be enforced.
In the case of the EU, registered designs last five years and are renewable multiple times for a total
protection of 25 years (OHIM, 2013b). To qualify, there should be no prior design that is identical (and
different jurisdictions may not even allow prior disclosure by the designer himself or herself), the design
should be non-obvious, and the ornamental features of the design should be visible when the product is in
use. Usually, registered designs are intended for aesthetic features. Parties infringing registered designs
can be prevented from using / commercialising the design or otherwise punished to recoup damages (UK
Intellectual Property Office, 2014a).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
329 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Patents
The registration of a patent gives the owner the right to exclude others from making, using, or selling
an invention. A patent provides the holder with a limited monopoly over a defined period in exchange for
contributing the underlying knowledge of the invention to the public state of the art. Although patent
protection is a right granted by government, the enforcement of patent infringement is deemed a civil
matter and must, in the vast majority of cases, be pursued at the expense of the patent holder. Patents are
also referred to as utility, functional or mechanical patents in some jurisdictions. Patents often protect
solutions to technological innovations that take the form of processes or products; however, in some
jurisdictions they may also be in the form of business methods, software, or even living organisms. The
base requirements for patenting an invention is that it must be novel, have utility, have some inventive
step, be non-obvious, and must be replicable by someone skilled in the art.(WIPO, 2008)
Given that functional aspects of a device cannot be protected by design IP, patents serve a vital role in
protecting the novel elements of products that also may have design context. Registered designs and
patents are often filed for the same product, the former covering the appearance and the latter the function
(Cook, 2007).
Utility models
A utility model, sometimes defined as “petty patent” or “innovation patent”, provides the right holder
the right to prevent others from using or selling the protected invention for a defined period of time. The
requirements for filing a utility model are significantly less stringent than those for filing a patent, as the
size of the “inventive step” required must attain only a much lower threshold and what examination is done
of an application is brief and more cursory. Given that the protection period (7-10 years, non-renewable)
and the examination period are much shorter than that of a patent, utility models cost significantly less than
patents. Utility models, however, are only issued by some national patent offices, such as Germany, China
and Japan, and have a much more limited geographic scope. They also have more limited scope in
protection since they are not examined for novelty and can be invalidated more easily (Thomä and Bizer,
2013). Companies generally see them as a much more convenient means of establishing priority for
incremental inventions, using them more as a method of strategic disclosure than as an exclusionary right.
In the role of providing priority, firms often use utility models, with the full knowledge that they carry
limited protection from infringement, in order to protect their freedom to operate. A utility model is a
certified document that commits the invention to the larger body of prior art, thereby preventing others
from patenting the invention (Peters et al., 2013). Since utility models are less costly and easier to obtain,
they can be a more agile tool to use when the design of a product will inevitably change in a term that it
much shorter than the life of a patent or when designers intend product intervals to be naturally short
(Byma and Leiponen, 2006).
Trademarks
A trademark is any sign, word, logo, etc., used to distinguish products and services from competitors
of the applicant. Trademarks indicate (visually) the source of the product or service. The term of
trademark protection continues indefinitely until such time that the trademark either is abandoned or loses
its distinguishing feature by becoming a generic term. The violation of trademark rights (passing off a good
or service as someone else’s by using their trademark) is subject to trademark infringement. It could also
be considered infringement if a trademark is not exactly the same but similar enough to cause confusion
among consumers (Durkin and Schirk, 2011).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
330 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Trademark and design are often closely and indelibly interlinked in the minds of consumers (Miaoulis
and d'Amato, 1978). For this reason, trademarks often figure strongly in product strategy. Design
protection allows firms the time to establish an identity in relation to a product without the worry of
imitation. If the product design endures as a symbol of the firm, then the firm can maintain trademark
protection almost indefinitely (Brean, 2008).
Copyrights
A copyright protects the form of artistic creation by protecting authors’ literary work or the output of
creative artists in the form of music, films, paintings, images, computer software, etc. The owner has the
exclusive right to distribute the work and reproduce, adapt, display, or perform it, or authorise others to do
so. Copyright does not protect the underlying ideas, only the form of the creation (WIPO, 2008). For
industrial designs that qualify as eligible copyrightable subject matter such as graphics, copyright
protection may function equally well, given that the protection of a copyright extends 70 after the death of
the owner; significantly longer than the maximum of 25 years afforded to registered designs. Many have
argued that fashion design should be similarly protected under copyright (Holton, 2014, Lahore, 1971,
Miller, 2014, Roth and Jacoby, 2009, Saidman, 2007, Stevens, 2012, Tsai, 2005, Xia, 2010). In some
countries, copyright protection is not available for functional articles (such as fashion or automotive parts)
even though aesthetically pleasing where the artistic features cannot be separated either physically or
conceptually.
Software and internet webpage designs are, however, covered by copyright in many countries. The
Court of Justice of the European Union recently ruled that while the functionality of a program cannot be
protected under copyright, the reproduction of a part of a manual, whether that be in a printed manual, and
online document, or an onscreen representation of a program itself, may constitute copyright infringement.
This finding, and its subsequent enforcement by the Court of Appeal for England and Wales, sought to
limit the scope whereby software developers could claim infringement and stifle competition (Gervais and
Derclaye, 2012). However, it has resulted in a realisation that copyright alone is insufficient to protect
software and must be complemented with registered designs to protect notable features of appearance as
well as patents for functional innovations (Silverman, 2014).
Countries considered in the study
Canada. The Canadian Intellectual Property Office (CIPO) is the agency responsible for IP regulation
and registration of patents, trademarks, industrial designs and copyrights in Canada. In Canada, industrial
designs are defined as “the visual features of shape, configuration, pattern or ornament, or any combination
of these features, applied to a finished article.” Such a design may be of a common object that, in and of
itself, has no functional novelty but does have an original appearance. The appeal to the eye is the key to
novelty. An idea, a method of construction, the materials used in the construction of an article or the
function of an article cannot be registered. In Canada, there is no time limit for registering an industrial
design if the design has never been published but if it has been published, the registration must be within
12 months of publication. The exclusivity is for a period of five years, which can be renewed for an
additional five years (Canadian Intellectual Property Office, 2001).
France. France has recently experienced significant growth in design IP. Although the Institut
National de la Propriété Industrielle (INPI) is the national agency responsible for administering IP, much
of the increase in applications has been filed under the broader Office for Harmonisation in the Internal
Market (OHIM) or World Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO) 272 schemes. The Compagnie
Nationale des Conseils en Propriété industrielle (CNCPI), which represents patent attorneys in France,
recommends companies and research centres bundle the various forms of protection available to them
(patents, trademarks, designs and models, domain names, etc.) and encourages the development of an
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
331 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
“intellectual property culture” in France (Compagnie Nationale des Conseils en Propriété industrielle,
2014).
Regarding design IP in particular, French companies file approximately 7% of all community designs
(see trends section below), which CNCPI feels is lower than what would be expected given the size of the
French economy, “leaving foreign companies to monopolise protection in the design field.” While French
copyright law is strong, it is not able to protect designs in all circumstances. Thus French copyright for
design protection may work for firms focusing exclusively on the French market, but “the informal nature
of copyright protections and the difficulties in establishing priority dates for first use make it difficult for
these firms to defend themselves in the face of infringement claims filed by firms empowered with the
more formal rights of a registered design.”(Compagnie Nationale des Conseils en Propriété industrielle,
2014)
Germany. Germany has the largest export economy in Europe. A high proportion of Germany’s
exports are manufactured products that rely heavily on design to differentiate them from cheaper, lower
quality products. The latest relevant law on design regulation in Germany is the Regulation of
2 January 2014 for Further Modernisation of the Design Act and Introduction of the Invalidity Procedure
in Design Matters. The German Patent and Trademark Office (DPMA) is national agency responsible for
patents, utility models, registered designs, and trademarks. In the case of registered designs and utility
models, the DPMA checks only if the application forms and definitions conform to the respective
requirements; it does not examine the character of the invention or design itself nor does it test the novelty
of the concept (DPMA, 2014).
United Kingdom. The system on intellectual property rights promoted by the United Kingdom seems
to offer strong protection. In 2014, the UK Parliament amended the intellectual property laws with special
attention to the protection of designs (HM Government, 2014).
A Registered Design in the United Kingdom can give rise to a valuable intellectual property right that
can serve as a basis of an infringement action against other parties. The registration of a design requires
that the design be new and have an individual character. The United Kingdom also excludes certain items
from registration as a design if the design does not fall under the legal definition, if the design is offensive,
if the design consists of certain protected flags and international emblems and if the design elements are
solely dictated by the product's technical function (UK Intellectual Property Office, 2006).
Italy. Italy provides a designs protection in line with the harmonisation requirements of EU Directive
98/71/EC. The exclusive right takes effect from the date of filing of the application and has a validity of 5
years, renewable for other four terms of 5 years, up to a maximum of 25 years. The registration protects the
appearance of a product, but there are no specific aesthetic requirements 273.
In accordance with the cumulus option provided by the EU Directive, the Italian IP code provides
rules for the relationships to utility models and copyrights. While designs protect just the formal
appearance, utility models protect the functional appearance. The same form can be protected both by
utility model and by design at the same time, but the two IP rights cover different objects and scopes.
A registered design may also be eligible for protection under the law of copyright, but only for
designs which meet two further requirements: creative character and artistic value. In this case, the validity
of the protection is 70 years after the author’s death, as per general copyright rules. The Italian IP code
does not provide for unregistered design protection.
To enhance the use of design protection at the enterprises level, especially for SMEs, after the design
registration fees, the renewal fees are due just from the second five-year period.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
332 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Japan. As the first country to ratify the Anti-Counterfeiting Trade Agreement (ACTA), Japan has
generally had a proactive stance in intellectual property protection on the global stage (Office of the United
States Trade Representative, 2012). Given Japan’s evolution over the past half century from a low-cost
producer to a developer of high technology and high-concept design goods, Japanese firms have taken
leading positions on both patent and design registry lists. This is largely due to the benefits of the Designs
Act. The Designs Act dates back to April 13, 1959, and it was amended with the revisions of Act No. 63 of
2011 (WIPO, 2014c). In addition to many of the protections afforded by other national patent laws, the
Japanese law allows design registrations to be held secret for up to three years at the request of the filing
party. There are also provisions by which designs may not be granted by the Japanese government, such as
any design that is liable to injure public order or morality. Japanese law also acts in a manner similar to
trademark protections as it prohibits any design that is liable to create confusion with an article pertaining
to another person's business (Japan Patent Office, 2014). This differentiation is a de facto form of trade
dress protection 274.
United States. In the United States, industrial designs are protected to varying degrees under design
patent law, copyright law, and trademark and unfair competition law. For the United States Patent and
Trademark Office (USPTO), a design consists of “visual ornamental characteristics embodied in, or
applied to, an article of manufacture.” As the design manifests itself in its visual characteristics, a “design
patent” (US version of a registered design) application may concern itself with the “configuration or shape
of an article, to the surface ornamentation applied to an article, or to the combination of configuration and
surface ornamentation.”(USPTO, 2012) Whoever invents any new, original, and ornamental design for an
article of manufacture may obtain a patent therefor. The term of protection has been 14 years from the
granting date. However, this term has been increased to 15 years from the granting date for applications
that are filed on or after May 13, 2015. 275 There is an area of overlap between Copyright and Design Patent
Statutes where an author/inventor can secure both a Copyright and a Design Patent. Thus, an ornamental
design may be copyrighted as a work of art and may also be the subject matter of a Design Patent. It is the
policy of the Patent and Trademark Office to permit the inclusion of a copyright notice in a Design Patent
application, and thereby any patent issuing therefrom 276.
A design patent and a trademark may be obtained on the same subject matter. The U.S. courts have
held that the underlying purpose and essence of patent rights are separate and distinct from those pertaining
to trademarks, and that no right accruing from the one is dependent upon or conditioned by any right
concomitant to the other. Accordingly, the use of trademarks in design patent application specifications is
permitted under limited circumstances 277.
South Korea. The Republic of Korea has the Industrial Design Protection Act or Act No. 951 of
December 31, 1961, as amended up to Act No. 9764 of June 9, 2009 (WIPO, 2014a). Design includes the
“shape, pattern, colour or a combination of these in an article that produces an aesthetic impression in the
sense of sight.” The term of protection is 15 years from the granting date. Two categories of design
applications are available in South Korea: normal examination designs (substantive) and non-examination
designs (non-substantive). Non-examination designs are restricted to two-dimensional products such as
wrapping paper and/or those with a short life cycle, for example fashion-dependent goods such as clothing
(IP Australia, 2014).
China. China's rapid economic rise led to it joining the World Trade Organisation (WTO) in 2001,
and this has contributed to major reforms in its intellectual property laws. Since then, China has introduced
legislation covering every aspect of the protection of IP. Chinese authorities have traditionally relied
heavily on the local registration characteristics and history of an item, whereby designs and trademarks
commonly known in other parts of the world were registered in China by parties other than the recognised
owners, because there was no evidence inside the Chinese domain. China has, however, put great effort
into conforming to international norms and treaty standards.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
333 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
As has been the case in other countries, the importance of reciprocal protection of IPRs grows as the
country generates more of its own IP. China’s emergence as a developer of design and technology
intellectual properties has brought about stronger enforcement of rights for IPRs held by both foreign and
domestic entities. Enforcement methods in China can vary from civil prosecution to governmental
administrative action and customs seizure for cases of wilful infringement (UK Intellectual Property
Office, 2014b).
The EU. The European Union established the Office of Harmonisation in the International Market
(OHIM), a central agency for the administration of trademarks and designs, in 1994 (European
Commission, 1994). The collective protection of design within the EU started in 1998 through the Design
Directive followed by the Design Regulation of 2001 with the eventual purpose of a European design
intellectual property regime. The Directive on the Legal Protection of Designs (European Commission,
1998) sets minimal standards for the eligibility and scope of protection for industrial design across Europe,
but also provides leeway in allowing member states to independently regulate registration, renewal, and
invalidation of design IP within their own borders so long as it meets those minimal standards. The
necessity of a single form of design protection that would allow goods embodying designs to circulate
inside the internal market led the EU to enact the Community Design Regulation (CDR) in 2002. The CDR
introduced the concept of Registered and Unregistered Community Designs (RCD and UCD, respectively).
While both enable the holder the ability to protect their design throughout the EU, the UCD is of a shorter
duration (3 years) and offers only limited protection against duplication, whereas the RCD offers
protection for a period of five years from the date of filing and can be renewed every five years for a
maximum of 20 years of protection. The other main difference between RCD and UCD is that RCD aims
to protect against both deliberate copying and the independent development of a similar design. UCD only
prevents intentional copying; if a second designer can demonstrate that she or he had no prior awareness of
the existence of the protected design and had created the design independently, there are no grounds for
infringement. Nevertheless, both forms of design protection have to meet the same conditions to be valid
(OHIM, 2013b).
It is interesting to note that Art. 8 (1) of the CDR states that “Community design shall not subsist in
features of appearance of a product which are solely dictated by its technical function.” This language is
common in design legislation so as to preclude the use of registered designs as de facto patents (European
Commission, 2002).
Major design areas
Registered designs are classified using the Locarno system, except in Canada. The Locarno
Agreement of 1968 established a means for classifying registered designs. This allows all participating
countries to use a common framework for indexing the nature of designs submitted. This benefits all by
allowing for easier search for establishing novelty. The classification system reflects the function of the
object being classified, and while this is similar in nature to the system of classifying patents, there is no
concordance between the two. Thus, a product may have a Locarno number that is vastly different from
patents describing the component parts therein. Likewise, the Locarno number speaks to the function of the
design being registered, not the industry wherein the object will be marketed, so Locarno classifications
may not be an accurate mapping of how designs are representative of certain industries. Although Canada
and the US (for U.S. design patents issued after May 6, 1997) are not signatories of the Locarno
Agreement, the US does assign Locarno classification numbers in addition to their own classification codes
so as to facilitate international searches.
Figure 6.2. The top design categories for each country in our sample as ranked by the count of
industrial designs filed at OHIM or through national and international routes, respectively, from 2009-2011
illustrates the top two Locarno classes of industrial designs by the representative countries in our sample.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
334 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
In the first column for each country is the listing of RCDs applied for through OHIM for protection within
the EU, whereas the second column is the combined listing of national and WIPO international filings. We
can see that there are five major categories:
•
Clothes, textiles and accessories
•
Electricity and lighting
•
Furniture and household goods
•
ICT and audio-visual, and
•
Tools and machines
Figure 6.2.
The top design categories for each country in our sample as ranked by the count of industrial
designs filed at OHIM or through national and international routes, respectively, from 2009-2011
Source: OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2013.
Although leisure and education was Canada’s top category for non-EU registrations, the category did
not rate as highly for any other country and did not amount to a significant portion of overall application
filings. Therefore, we excluded it from the list.
This informs us that design is a strong element in the consumer goods arena, specifically for products
we might assign to the categories of fashion and decor—industries that have long been associated with
design. Information and communications technology, on the other hand, is not one that we consider
immediately as a design domain; however, within that domain is the subclass of “Screen displays and
icons”, wherein any representation of an electronic control interface would be registered.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
335 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Commonalities of design IP regimes
Table 6.1 gives a summary of design IP regimes across the sample countries. All nine countries have
laws and regulation that rule and protect industrial design. While there are differences across the various
definitions and enactments of design protection, there are also a number of notable similarities.
Specifically, the OHIM and various countries of the EU share many commonalities. This stems from the
fact that EU Directive 98/71/EC obliged each of the EU Member States to harmonise the substantive rules
on the protection of industrial design in an effort to establish uniform laws in a sector characterised in the
past by a diversity of approaches.
The definition of design varies from system to system: there are countries where the definition is
complete and exhaustive, such as Japan, UK, France and Italy, countries where the definition is, in the
view of some, more ambiguous or simplistic (USA, Germany, Canada, Korea and China). Where the
definition of design is not as clear as the protection rules, interpretative problems have led to difficulties of
application.
Table 6.1. Representation of similarities and differences of design rights across sample countries
CN
Design Patent
France
FR
Designs and Models
Germany
DE
Designs
Italy
IT
Design and Model
Japan
JP
Design
Korea
KR
Design
UK
UK
Registered Design
EU
US
Design Patent
Registered
OHIM Community Design
●
●
F
10
F
5x5
F
5x5
F
5x5
F
20
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
G
14/15
●
F
5x5
F
15
F
5x5
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
Unregistered Option
Multiple applications
Online application
5x2
Hague Agreement
G
Accession of
Treaty
Locarno Agreement
●
●
●
Substantive examination
●
method
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
Years x number of
terms
China
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
F = from filing
G = from grant
Industrial Design
Symbols / Graphics
CA
whole
Name
Canada
US
Term of
Protection
Definition of Design
part
C
ou
n
try
Country designation code
Comparison of Design IP Regimes
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
●
Source: authors’ compilation.
Note: The United States Senate gave advice and consent to ratification of the Hague Agreement on 7 December 2007. On 18
December 2012, title I of the Patent Law Treaties Implementation Act of 2012 was enacted to implement the provisions of the 1999
Geneva Act of the Hague Agreement Concerning the International Registration of Industrial Designs (“Hague Agreement”). (Public
Law 112-211, Dec. 18, 2012). Specific implementing provisions are found, for example, in 35 USC 381-390. On 13 February 2015,
the United States deposited its instrument of ratification for Geneva Act of the Hague Agreement. On 2 April 2015, the U.S. Patent
and Trademark Office published its final rule to implement the Hague Agreement. 80 Fed.Reg. 17,918 (Apr.2, 2015). The treaty will
go into effect on 13 May 2015 with respect to the United States. As previously noted, U.S. design patents resulting from applications
filed on or after 13 May 2015 will have a 15 year term.
The terms of protection generally range around 20-25 years. Even though each county may have its
own definition of industrial design and the term of protection, there is a debate about the appropriate model
for design IP harmonisation, especially the line between copyright and design rights. One side of the
debate proposes that since design focuses on the visual impact of a product, it is much closer to creative
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
336 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
work than invention, so copyright law could be suitable for design protection as compared to other
intellectual property forms (Rahman, 2014, Afori, 2008).
Encouraging protection of design
As design allows firms to differentiate themselves and their products, thereby allowing them to
appropriate superior value compared with more “commoditised” product or service, protection of design
rights may give incentives to innovate and invest in design in both manufacturing and service industries.
International treaties and industrial design
Different international treaties concern standardisation of intellectual property rights; however, there
is not a clear definition of their legal protection with regard to design (Suthersanen, 2010) because different
jurisdictions have differing classifications of industrial design and the debate over the nature of design is
still open. Nevertheless, industrial design is mentioned in different international treaties.
The Berne Convention: The Berne Convention was the first major international copyright treaty,
became effective in 1886 and defined industrial design as an artistic work (Schickl, 2013). Industrial
design is not specifically regulated under the Berne Convention, but it is conceived as a “work of applied
art” [Art. 2(1)] and leaves it to the discretion of member countries whether they want to protect industrial
design as applied art [Art. 2(7)]. The convention provides reciprocal rights for protection of industrial
designs, such that if an industrial design is protected under the laws of one signatory country, it shall
receive the same protection under similar legislation in other signatory states. If a signatory state’s law
does not pronounce on the protection of industrial design, the Berne Convention offers protection under
copyright law, as it considers industrial design to be artistic work (Schickl, 2013).
The Paris Convention: The first international treaty for the regulation of patents, the Paris
Convention was signed in 1883 and the last revision was made in 1967 (Schickl, 2013). Under the Paris
Convention, industrial design was dealt with as industrial property and was accorded a patent-like
protection. It stipulated that nationals of contracting states must be afforded equal rights of protection as
nationals of other contracting states in those jurisdictions. An applicant can file separate applications with
each office directly to obtain protection in multiple jurisdictions, but gains protection from the time the
first application was filed so long as the follow-on applications were filed within 12 months for patents and
utility models, 6 months for industrial designs and trademarks. It also stipulated that industrial designs
must be afforded protection in a contracting state even if products derived from those designs were not
manufactured in that nation (WIPO, 2014d). This was an effort to lower barriers trade.
The TRIPS Agreement: The Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights
(TRIPS) is administered by the World Trade Organisation (WTO) and became effective in 1994. The
TRIPS does not provide a definition of industrial design but merely defines the requirements and scope of
its protection. Language of the TRIPS Agreement is relatively sparse regarding industrial designs.
Nonetheless, it does integrate design rights into the larger canon of law providing global protection of
intellectual property. It also establishes a minimum of ten years of protection for an industrial design that
meets novelty and other requirements.
The Hague Agreement: Concluded in 1925 and revised in 1999, the Hague Agreement provided for
a single point of application for members of all signatory states. It establishes an initial five-year protection
period for industrial designs at the international level, with the possibility of multiple renewal periods. The
advantage is that design owners can obtain protection for their designs with a single registration, thereby
minimising formalities and expense. An applicant can obtain protection for up to 100 industrial designs for
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
337 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
products belonging to one and the same class and in multiple jurisdictions with a single application filed
through WIPO.
The above agreements and treaties provide holders of design-related intellectual property with a
coherent set of rules and regulations whereby they can expect to receive fair and unbiased treatment so
long as they work within the established system of a member state.
Differences between IP regimes
Despite the implementation of various treaties and harmonisation efforts, there still remain many
differences between the regimes of the various sample countries.
German and French courts seemingly tend to be quick and proactive in protecting design IP. This is
largely due to the fact that the German and French laws assign greater weight to the authors’ and inventors’
rights. In Italy, in the field of industrial law the use of summary (or urgent) proceedings is statistically very
frequent. It is characterised by the full freedom of forms, though with due discussion between the parties
and greater speed of the decision. In most cases, the urgent decision is not followed by an ordinary trial
process. German design owners tend to be more aware of the options available for design IPR and thus
make higher use of the system whereas UK innovators tend to opt for other means of protecting their
designs such as confidentiality agreements, lead-time and brand awareness (BOP Consulting, 2011).
One issue with the need to be first-to-market is that it tends to result in shorter product lifecycles.
Short product cycles in conjunction with arduous application processes can also deter design owners from
registering their IP. This has been identified as one reason for the low rate of design IP adoption in the
United Kingdom (BOP Consulting, 2011). In an effort to combat a similar issue and to aid its prominent
fashion industry, the French IP office introduced a simplified procedure for registering designs (BOP
Consulting, 2011). The changes appear to have had significant influence, both on design owners’
perception of the system and on filing rates. In Italy the IP code envisages special provisions to address
issues related to the short life cycle of a product and the processing time for the design application: the the
exclusive right takes effect from the date of filing of the application so the designs holder has the right to
base a legal action from the filing application date.
In China, patents and trademarks registered in other countries are not afforded mutual protection as
defined under international treaties, as mentioned above. This is because China’s trademark and patent
regimes rely on filing as a means of establishing priority; evidence of prior use or invention carries less
weight than an application filing. For this reason, China has not always recognised the existence of a
design outside the country as grounds for invalidity. This has led to a number of cases, most notably in the
copyright and trademark realms but also in the design realm, in which companies with recognised designs,
brands, or trademarks have seen IP disputes arise when attempting to enter the Chinese market. While
there are valid appeals processes, those processes are costly, time consuming, and—as with any legal
process—uncertain. (Canadian Trade Commissioner Service, 2014).
The differences between the intellectual property regimes among the sample countries can be
attributed to several factors—from cultural, to political, to economic orientation of the sample states. An
example could be the differences in the design IP regimes of France, Germany, and the UK. Up until
recently, infringers faced more severe sanctions in Germany than in the UK. The received wisdom at the
time was that France and Germany had laws and courts that placed a higher importance on the rights of
authors or inventors. Furthermore, the cost of enforcement of those rights had been consistently lower in
France and Germany than in the UK, which required a civil process (BOP Consulting, 2011). However, in
2014, prompted by the Hargreaves report (2011), the UK followed suit and declared that the intentional
copying of a registered design would now be subject to criminal prosecution (HM Government, 2014). The
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
338 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
UK law, however, did not stipulate that the underlying design IP must be re-examined, nor did it make the
criminal conviction subject to the ultimate validity of the infringed IP.
Participation in global value chains and trade can also be significantly shaped by differences in IP
regimes. For example, if a design protected in a specific country is not necessarily protected in another
country, there will be no rights to claim against design infringement in the country where a design is not
protected. On the other hand, enterprises with significant design rights in a country of origin may opt to not
expand to another country because of the lack in protection of design-related IP.
The differences in the term of protection also may influence intellectual property strategies of owners.
The different terms structures may mean that the design IP is no longer protected in one jurisdiction while
at the same time being valid in another. The enterprise that owns the design-related IP could therefore be
subject to additional expenses to resolve the situation. Infringement of design will no longer be protected
after the term has run out in one of the jurisdictions in which the owner operates.
Design IP complementarities
IP protection mechanisms allow the inventor/innovator to appropriate most of the returns from the
initial innovation investment by excluding third parties from using the property. As such, the overriding
role for protection mechanisms is to ensure exclusivity, thus, appropriability is the primary a concern for
inventors. With regard to design, the output of inventive activity is often a non-excludable form of
knowledge based capital (KBC). In the absence of an effective formal IP system, invention and innovation
may be stifled if firms are unable to use IP protection mechanisms.
Across most legal jurisdictions, several IP protection mechanisms exist to exclude third parties from
appropriating innovation (Rammer, 2002). These mechanisms can be grouped into two broad categories.
The first is formal protection mechanisms, which rely on regulatory systems to protect IP. Formal IP
protection mechanisms encompass a range of legal mechanisms such as patents, trademarks, industrial
designs, utility models, and copyright (Rammer, 2002). These formal protection mechanisms act as
incentives for innovators to invest in technology development, generate new knowledge, and foster
diffusion (Rammer, 2002). As these have been discussed in the prior sections, we will not treat them
further here.
The second category of protection mechanisms falls under the category of informal protection
instruments. The mechanisms are primarily extra-legal measures not enforceable through formal regulatory
mechanisms. Unlike formal mechanisms, enforcement is not guaranteed by the state (Rammer, 2002).
Informal mechanisms can encompass a range of strategies, tacit knowledge, confidentiality agreements,
lead-time (first mover advantage), or complexity (of design) that are defined as “alternative” or informal
IP.
Informal protection mechanisms
Firms may choose from a range of “alternative” or informal appropriation mechanisms, such as leadtime, complexity, tacit knowledge, or confidentiality agreements to bundle with design IP. Informal
protection is relatively weak compared to formal protection when it comes to enforcement through the
legal system, but it can be highly effective, lower cost, and in some cases may carry less risk of “inventing
around.” (Hall et al., 2012)
Lead-time
Lead-time—otherwise known as “product first to market” or “speed to market”—is the advantage
provided by getting to market ahead of the competition. This practice allows firms to gain an early marketENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
339 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
share and establish themselves as market leaders. Quite often, this results in a firm establishing its product
as the de facto market standard. All of these advantages provide the leading firm superior opportunities to
appropriate value. By establishing itself as the market leader or the exemplar after which all other products
are measured, the leading firm will be able to appropriate superior rents even when the product market
becomes commoditised by imitators (Boldrin and Levine, 2013). Given a hypothetical situation wherein
there was a total absence of intellectual property protection such that unlimited duplication would carry
penalty, the manufacture of duplicates would nonetheless require time. Before a competitive equilibrium
would be reached, the leader would be able to charge a price premium. Despite both the theoretical and
practical advantages provided by lead time, it is difficult to quantify—since build-quality, brand value and
consumer perception all factor in to the price advantage—and also hard to qualify since interviews and
surveys often suffer from ex ante or ex post biases.
By analysing the relevant importance of different appropriability mechanisms as reported by
respondents from Germany, Belgium, Denmark, Luxembourg, Ireland, Norway and the Netherlands,
Arundel (2001) finds that Lead-time is deemed to be the most effective mechanism by far for appropriating
value from innovations. This is by far the most important factor, with secrecy, design complexity, patents
and design registration following in order of decreasing relevance.
Complexity
Complexity of design is classified as an informal method of protection. Ichijo (2007) illustrates this
for some consumer electronics products: Sharp put tremendous efforts into making imitation of its LCD
TV sets time consuming and difficult. While the complexity factor may appear to be only relevant to the
realm of technology products, it should be noted that complexity has been the hallmark of designers and
craftsmen for centuries. The technique of engraving fine intersecting and overlapping lines on the plates of
banknotes or stamps, also known as guilloche, is an example of complexity that was also used by
manufacturers of jewellery, fine art craft works, timepieces, and weaponry in order to provide a superior
appearance and set them apart from simple imitations (see Samuelson and Scotchmer, 2002 for further
details and examples).
Tacit knowledge
Tacit knowledge is knowledge that is difficult to codify and transmit without high interaction between
the transmitter and receiver of the knowledge. While many elements of a design may be evident from the
appearance of it, this does not necessarily mean that competitors have the knowledge or abilities to recreate
the product expressing that design. Studies have provided evidence that, in general, firms place a low value
or importance on formal IPRs such as patents or registered designs (Cohen et al., 2000, Gemser and
Leenders, 2001, Hall et al., 2012). While many employers may see this as a call for secrecy and restriction
on employees, most firms view their knowledge workers as vital resources who are directly tied to firm
success by virtue of, among other factors, their tacit knowledge. In order to protect their resources, these
firms tend to rely more on rewards and incentives than on restrictive measures. By building a lasting
relationship with their knowledge workers, whether employees or contractors, they contribute to the
company’s ability to maintain its competitive advantage.
Confidentiality agreements
Both lead-time and complexity involve elements of secrecy or confidentiality, the failure of which
would allow competitors to pre-empt or imitate the as-yet unreleased product. While the nature of design is
that the design elements may be fully revealed in the product once it is released, the key to value
appropriation is to maintain the advantage that informal factors allow. By using such things as nondisclosure agreements, non-compete agreements and intellectual property assignment agreements, firms
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
340 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
can protect and control the information about impending products that the techniques that were used to
produce them. This becomes more important as firms engage in larger sets of collaborators, suppliers,
contractors, and distributors in order to address larger markets. Whereas at one time such matters would be
taken care of with an oath and a handshake, in this era one must rely upon tangible documents in order to
uphold and enforce such agreements. For this reason, even in pure design service industries and others that
may not rely heavily on technological innovations, non-disclosure agreements are ubiquitous.
Factors explaining selection of IP protection mechanisms
Various factors go into the strategic decisions surrounding the choice of IP mechanisms a firm uses to
protect its innovations and extract superior rents. Teece (1986) explains that a mixture of three factors
drives profits: appropriability regimes, complementary assets, and how strong the dominant paradigm is in
the market sector in which the firm operates. The appropriability regime is the integrated network of
formal and informal protection mechanisms as discussed above. A tight appropriability regime will make it
harder for competitors to imitate the product, providing obstacles or penalties that act as barriers and allow
the firm to retain greater profits (Teece, 1986).
Complementary assets represent all of the elements throughout the value chain that a company needs
to develop, manufacture, and successfully market a product. This can include access to components,
manufacturing facility, upstream or downstream supply chain, distribution, marketing, sales and support
networks. Complementary assets can also mean access to knowledge stocks, IP, or talent. In a good
scenario, a firm has access to all, but exclusive access to some of them—thereby creating a bottleneck that
a competitor must overcome. Teece (1986) cautions that even when a firm has the full advantage of a
strong appropriability regime in its favour, if it cannot muster the full value chain of complementary assets,
it would be at a market disadvantage.
There is also the issue of dominant paradigm. Consider Tesla Motors, the maker of the well-received
electric cars. Tesla had a strong IP portfolio, with both patents and design rights, as well as informal
protection mechanisms. The industry had, however, two dominant paradigms that the company had to
overcome: the support (fuel) structure was for gasoline vehicles, and in most states in the US it is illegal
for automobile manufacturers to sell directly to the consumer. Tesla has worked to establish networks of
widely spaced charging stations to overcome the former and continues to work on challenging the laws that
restrict their abilities in the latter case. This shows that there is not just one key condition for success and
that firms must take a more strategic approach to integrating formal and informal mechanisms into its IP
decision process.
There have been few studies examining the integration of design IP with different formal and informal
mechanisms. Examining data from the French portion of the CIS-3 survey, Mairesse and Mohnen (2004)
compared the level of use of various protection mechanisms by manufacturing and service firms. Patents,
secrecy, and design registration all fell consistently behind trademarks, complexity, and lead-time in terms
of frequency of use (Mairesse and Mohnen, 2004). Baldwin et al. (1999) also investigated firms’ usage of
IP mechanisms through a direct survey of businesses in the communications, financial services, and
technical business services sectors. They found that less than half of the respondents made use of any IPRs.
Of those that did make use of IPRs, copyrights and trademarks were the predominant tool used. Lead-time
and complexity were considered far more useful than any of the formal mechanisms.
These studies used survey methodology to assess the importance or usage of various IP protection
mechanisms. Survey methodology makes it difficult to accurately measure the level of integration or the
effectiveness of any given part of an integrated strategy. However, it is clear from these reports that design
IP does not play a pivotal role in the IP strategies of the respondents or their firms. Part of the issue may be
the perception on the part of the manager that seeking design rights is too costly in terms of time or money,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
341 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
or that the ownership of IP brings with it liabilities and the potential for infringement actions. On the other
hand, managers may also be attributing success to lead-time and complexity and downplaying the
advantages provided by design IP. Moreover, none of the studies took into account that, in Europe at least,
unregistered design is a passive right that either was not given as options or was not considered by
respondents.
Trends in design outcomes, with a focus on registered designs
In this section, we will examine trends in registered designs. Below, we discuss the incidence of
registered design activity at the national and sectorial levels and describe whether and how some of this
activity has changed over time. We describe the activity of firms based in each country of our sample as
well as overall activity within each country. We then examine the primary sectors within each country.
Finally, we look at some of the top designers at the firm level and describe their IP bundling strategies.
To examine the overall trend of design registration without risk of overlapping registrations we are
using data from OHIM and the USPTO. While WIPO is yet another registry of design IP, given that only a
portion of our sample set are signatories of the Hague Agreement, there is a certain amount of irregularity
in WIPO participation wherein design holders may register both with WIPO under the Hague Agreement
and under other national protection mechanisms. It is for this reason that we focus on design IP filed solely
within the EU and US.
Overall trend of OHIM filings
Given that design regulation started under OHIM in 2002, we have the opportunity to see the early
stages of this regime. Given that the countries in our sample comprise the core of the European economy, it
is to be expected that in the early stages of OHIM’s development, they formed the highest percentage of
filings. However, as OHIM has become more established we see an increasing percentage of filings
coming from other actors. Nonetheless, we also see that the countries in our sample dictate the trend and
contribute the greatest proportion of filings.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
342 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.3.
The trend of overall design filings through OHIM
Source: OECD StatExtracts, 2014.
In Figure 6.3 we see that the overall trend of design registrations is increasing, albeit at a decreasing
rate compared to the early period. Much of the rapid increase was because of the initial adoption and
diffusion of the OHIM system. In Figure 6.4, we see the example of Italy, wherein national filings in 20032005 were higher than OHIM filings of Italian origin, but as Italian OHIM filings increased there was a
coincidental decrease in filings at the national patent office of Italy. This indicates a relatively rapid
adoption of the OHIM system of protecting designs as design owners seek the broader geographical
coverage provided by OHIM. However, we also note a relatively consistent amount of design registrations
with the national office. This is, in part, due to the unique situation wherein Italy’s laws provide the same
national protection for designs along as for copyright. This provides incentives for firms to file in parallel
so that they can enjoy this extended protection even after design protections under the OHIM regime have
expired.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
343 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.4.
Italian filings nationally and through OHIM
Source: Italian UIBM 2014; OHIM DesignView 2014.
Nonetheless, in Figure 6.4 we do observe that the overall rate of filings have decreased in Italy from
an initial peak in the sampling period, decreasing drastically and then settling out at a relatively steady
pace. This slow but steady rate of increase is what we have seen across the overall sample set. This may be
an indication that the adoption of design IP has reached a stable state and the growth in design registrations
is primarily a reflection of the overall growth of the economy.
Registered designs emanating from the sample countries—trends
As noted in the previous section, in Figure 6.5 we see a gradually increasing trend in applications for
design registrations in many of the sample countries. This represents the supply of overall stock of design
IP for the European community. Although this stock of IP is being constantly replenished, there is also the
depletion of stock due to designs reaching their expiration or, since registered designs must be renewed
every five years, the choice of owners not to renew.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
344 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.5.
OHIM Design Applications by country of origin
Source: OECD StatExtracts 2014.
These trends are depicted in Figure 6.6. Although we see the rate of applications increasing, the stocks
appear to be levelling out or decreasing, especially for the dominant countries Germany and Italy.
Figure 6.6.
OHIM Registered Designs by country of origin
Source: OECD StatExtracts 2014.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
345 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
In this figure, we note a slight growth trend over the ten-year period, but not very rapid growth, with
two notable exceptions. For Korean registrations, if one examines the designs closely, the vast majority of
them are in the area of consumer electronics in recent years and most of them emanate from one firm:
Samsung. Samsung’s rise to prominence in consumer electronic design (rather than pure outsourced
manufacturing of the past) thus accounts for much of the growth in Korean registrations, whereas other
sample countries tended to have a more stable registration patterns, probably due to the more stable
importance of design in their economies. Likewise, China is seeing a robust growth in the number of
registered designs as it shifts from a outsourced manufacturing economy to a design and production model
in its own right.
The other major market for design protection is the United States by filing through the USPTO. Given
the size of the US market, it is clear that the dominant contributor to US design patent registrations is the
US. Figure 6.7 shows the importance of US firms in the design market. 278 What is also notable, although
not surprising, is that Japan figures so prominently. Given that the US is one of Japan’s primary export
markets, it is only sensible that Japanese firms protect the designs of their products there.
Figure 6.7.
USPTO filings (log count, adjusted axis) for design patent applications from the sample set
Source: USPTO PTMT 2014.
There is, however, a greater subtlety to the dynamics of design registration in the US market if one
excludes the dominant US input. Figure 6.8 shows the relative proportion of design registrations by nonUS applicants. While Japan figures prominently, Germany and Korea—also major exporters to the US—
are strongly involved in design registration; however, the combined input of all other nations not selected
in this sample create a mass of design IP greater than that of any one of these major players. This indicates
that the market for design IP is both diverse and active.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
346 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.8.
Non-US participation in USPTO design patent registrations
Source: USPTO PTMT 2014.
Resource-based estimates of design output
The indicators we are examining have, so far, been represented on a per nation basis; however, the
relative positioning of the nations in terms of design-related registrations tells us as much about their
relative Gross Domestic Product (GDP) as it does about the design capacity of the nation. We thus sought a
means whereby we could normalise these data in order to bring them into context relative to the inherent
resources of the nations. As mentioned earlier, the GDP indicators are not significantly different from the
traces we have here, so we sought other means. Since designs are commonly registered by firms, we could
examine the data in that manner; however, the data on number of total enterprises by nation is
incomplete—both in terms of the nations we are examining and in terms of the years reported if the data
are available—such that we could not generate representative indicators. In addition, the variance in firm
sizes across nations, and thus the relative count of firms, might introduce additional error factors. Given
that design is a human artefact (Krippendorff, 1989), the population of any nation may be a good
measurable resource for design generation. For this reason, we feel it most appropriate to examine the
relative outputs of each sample country relative to its population. This weighting method can thus express
the innovative design output not on the basis of sheer brute force, but instead by the engagement of the
population.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
347 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.9.
Combined OHIM and USPTO design stocks by country of origin per million population
Source: USPTO PTMT 2014, OECD StatExtracts 2014, World Bank Database 2014).
Although we saw in Figure 6.8 that the US is the dominant leader in design279, when the populations
of those countries are factored in and registrations in both the US and the EU are taken into account, as
seen in Figure 6.9., the picture changes dramatically. The US falls behind Germany in designs per capita,
remaining just above Italy, France, and the UK. The latter group of countries have approximately the same
activity as Korea when normalised by population. Given the massive population of China, it is not
surprising that its design activity is less pronounced when normalised.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
348 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.10.
Per capita design output as measured by non-US originated design applications made to the
USPTO
Source: USPTO PTMT 2014, World Bank Data 2014.
Korea’s designs per capita become even more pronounced when one considers the US market alone
and excluding the overwhelming inputs of the US. In Figure 6.10.we see that, although Japan does retain a
leading position in terms of per capita output, Canada and Korea are strong in registering designs in the US
market. Given Canada’s proximity to the US, it is not surprising that this would be a natural market for the
design output of its relatively small population. Korea, on the other hand, with its powerhouse firms in the
audio-visual (televisions, computer displays, etc.) and telecommunications (mobile phones, tablet
computers, etc.) fields, also has a strong stake in the US consumer market despite its geographic distance
from them.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
349 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.11.
OHIM design applications by country of origin per capita
Source: OECD StatExtracts 2014, World Bank Data 2014.
Looking at the trend in relation to OHIM design applications when normalised by population, we
observe that German designers continue to dominate the space, while the rest of the European countries
(Italy, France, and Britain) remain clustered together, with a distinct lead over the non-European countries.
Much like the US, which dominates the North American market, the European players tend to focus
primarily on their home ground. Part of this is the simple fact that sales and exports are highly dependent
upon proximity and familiarity. Nonetheless, even in the European marketplace we see Korea making
definite gains and establishing itself as a rising power.
Alternative indicators of design activity
As previously stated herein, design is intrinsically linked to brand identity and the firms that own the
brands. Since trademarks can be words, statements, images or other elements, there is significant debate as
to whether they are a valid representation of design (Durkin and Schirk, 2011, Jackson, 2014, Miaoulis and
d'Amato, 1978). Trademarks can, however, be used to protect three-dimensional designs, and given the
longer protection of a trademark, the registration of three-dimensional trademarks could be an indicator of
those designs that firms may consider to be more significant or longer lasting. Other than articles
describing the legal frameworks under which three-dimensional trademarks can be implemented or how
they may conflict with design or other laws (Khoury, 2008, Li, 2012), there is no evidence that the value
proposition of these marks as perpetuating or representing design has been examined in literature. In light
of the consideration that this may, at some point, be an avenue for future research, we include here an
analysis of three dimensional trademark filings from 2003-2013.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
350 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.12.
Registration rates by country of origin of three-dimensional trademarks
Source: OECD StatExtracts 2014.
Indications are that the quantity of three-dimensional trademarks filed annually is too low to establish
any current trend, as seen in Figure 6.12. It does appear that Germany has previously been a frequent
source of registrations.
The major sectors in which designs are registered
Figure 6.13. is reproduced from the OECD Science, Technology, and Industry Scoreboard (OECD,
2013, p. 192) and shows the number of registered designs for the periods 2006-2008 and 2010-2012.
Sectors are identified on the basis of a taxonomy using information about the Locarno class in which
designs are registered. Please note that as mentioned above, the figure does not represent the sectors in
which the firms actually compete, but rather in which they register their designs. For example, if an
airplane manufacturer registered a design on a new seat, this would be classified as “furnishing” and not
“air frame manufacturing.”
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
351 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.13.
Number of OHIM registrations by Locarno Classification
Source: OECD StatExtracts 2014.
Note that the figure represents total designs registered; therefore, it should be expected not to have too
much movement between the two periods, as the only difference would be new registrations minus expired
registrations. Still, we see net inflows (growth of registrations) in clothing, ICTs, lighting, travel goods,
and medical equipment. We see net outflows in furnishing, packaging, sanitary equipment, household
goods, construction, transport, and adornments.
Regarding the participation from the sample countries in these sectors filed with OHIM, 280 the OECD
examines two major sectors more closely: transport, and ICTs, as shown in Figure 6.14. and Figure 6.15.
Transport is divided into ships/boats (top countries: France, Italy, UK), aircraft / space (France, USA,
Italy), cars (Germany, Japan, UK), and cycles / motorcycles (Germany, Japan, Italy). The ICT sector is
divided into data processing / recording equipment (top countries: USA, Germany, Japan), communication
devices (Korea, USA, Germany), and audio-visual devices (France, Japan, Germany). Among the other
countries, Canada is fairly active in ships, motorcycles, data processing equipment, and communication
devices. China is fairly active in cars, motorcycles, and all the ICT sectors.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
352 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Figure 6.14.
OHIM transport-related registered designs, 2010-2012
Source: OECD STI Scoreboard 2013.
Figure 6.15.
OHIM ICT and audiovisualrelated registered designs, 2010-2012
Source: OECD STI Scoreboard 2013.
Firm-level activity
Of course, most of the activity for registered designs actually takes place at the firm level and most of
the statistics we have discussed so far have been aggregated up to the country level or grouped by sector in
which the design was registered. In this section, we look more closely at trends in firm-level registered
design activity.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
353 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Bundling designs and patents (and possibly other forms of IP)
Whether for the fact that design can be expressed in a multitude of ways or that firms seek multiple
avenues to protect their knowledge-based capital, it is recognised that covering a singular design or
invention with multiple IPRs is prudent (Silverman, 2014). This practice, known as “bundling” IPRs, can
provide a more solid or longer-lasting protection of designs. While it is difficult to identify bundles without
painstaking, record-by-record analysis, it may be possible to identify bundling tendencies through the
analysis of trends in firms’ accumulation of various ratios of IP.
In an effort to illustrate and explore this activity, we undertook a comparative analysis of two firms
that have competed strongly against each other. These are two of the largest firms by market capitalisation
of two countries in our sample, Korea and the US. The two companies, which have carried on a wellpublicised series of lawsuits over the various merits, or lack thereof, of registered designs as well as
technology patents, are Apple Inc. and Samsung Electronics Co., Ltd. While the relationship between these
two companies is complex and multidimensional, given that they have both a competitive as well as a
supplier/customer relationship, matters came to a head shortly after Apple introduced the iPhone in 2007.
Apple claimed that Samsung products were intentional imitations of the highly successful iPhone, and later
iPad, designs (Cusumano, 2013).
Figure 6.16.
Ratios of design, trademark and patent registrations for Samsung and Apple over a 10-year
period
Source: OHIM DesignView 2014, OHIM TMview 2014, Questrel Intellectual Property Portal 2014.
In Figure 6.16. note that for the period 2003-2006 both companies had a relatively low ratio of
designs to patents. Apple added a significant number of designs to its portfolio in 2007 just ahead of the
iPhone release, and it also increased its collection of trademarks. Samsung, meanwhile, continued to
maintain its previous pattern of design, trademark and patent filings281. Samsung did commit itself to
capturing a significant portion of the smartphone market. By 2010, Samsung had released the first of its
Galaxy smartphones and immediately drew the attention of Apple. We see some evidence that Samsung
began bundling more in 2008, and that Apple, fresh off of registering numerous designs and trademarks
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
354 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
after the release of the iPhone and iPhone 2, continues to show significantly increased tendencies to
bundle. Included in this chart is a trend line of patenting activity for each firm, which tells us that the rate
of patenting did not decrease; in fact, patenting activities of both companies tend to increase
consistently 282. Given that patents are in the denominator of each ratio, and given that patenting is
generally increasing, this means that since 2007 Apple’s rate of increase in design registration and
trademarking—in most years, each of those activities individually—is in excess of the rate of increase in
the patents filed by the firm. Furthermore, the rate of bundling has generally been accelerating since 2009.
While we acknowledge that, given the 18-month (or more) blackout period that utility patent
applications 283 are subjected to, patents are a lagging indicator, we argue that the nature of patents requires
that they be filed significantly sooner than design registrations or trademarks, which may be filed just prior
to or even after the initial release to the public. This may result in much of the lag time between patent
filing and publication being negated. In any case, the overall increasing rate of patenting, even if lagged,
does not account for the greater increase in design and trademark registration activity. By all appearances,
both Apple and Samsung have altered their behaviour and have adopted some bundling tendencies.
Measures of design inputs
The general protocol for R&D input measures is the “Frascati Manual” (OECD, 2002). However, the
Frascati Manual takes a narrow view of design inputs (see paragraphs 22, 79, 84, and 110), according to
some (e.g. Moultrie and Livesey, 2014). Under that protocol, some design-related activities might be
excluded. Thus, there is a paucity of research connecting design investments or activity or inputs with
performance outputs.
Classification of input measures
However, in this section, we would like to take the small number of articles that exist on design
activity and classify them by their input measures (see Table 6.2.).
Design orientation by observation of organisation structure
These inputs are subjective measures that examine the internal organisation of the firms and where the
design function fits into it, if at all. In an examination of design orientation of firms, Black and Baker
(1987) measure greater design involvement within the NPD process in interviews with 61 executives in
Scottish engineering and industrial textile companies. They use the presence of an “aesthetic design” or
industrial design group at all as a proxy for “design orientation.” Ones with aesthetic design groups (very
few) are thought to be more design-oriented. In contrast, most of the small companies in their sample have
an “engineering design” group. The authors also measure whether the Managing Director of the company
had personal involvement in the design process or not. Similarly, Walsh et al. (1992), studying 100 firms
in different sectors worldwide, uses the existence of formal design activity, and whether such activity is
located inside marketing or engineering, as a measure of “design consciousness.”
Perceptual measures
In several cases, researchers simply ask managers to rate their investment qualitatively as growing or
shrinking, or other perceptions of the firms’ investments. For example, Chiva and Alegre (2009) survey
182 ceramic tile manufacturers in Spain and Italy in which they asked managers to rate their perceptions
about whether investment in design in the respondent’s company had increased or decreased (Chiva and
Alegre, 2009). Likewise, Dickson et al. (1995) surveys over 200 CEOs of rapidly growing companies
listed in Inc. magazine’s list of rapidly growing companies and asks them to rate their design activity in
several different categories, such as product/service design or packaging design on a range from “greatly
decreased” investment to “greatly increased” investment.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
355 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Table 6.2.
Reference
Input measures of design as sampled in literature (Authors’ compilation)
Category
Details
Design
involvement
within NPD
Design orientation
In interviews, existence of an “aesthetic design”
group
1992
Design
consciousness
Design orientation
The existence of formal design activity in 100
companies, and whether such formal activity is
located inside marketing or engineering
Roy and Potter
1993
Costs
of
design work
Actual
expenditures
Survey of 221 UK SMEs in manufacturing
(cross-industry) that received a government
grant to employ a professional design consultant
answering questions about total expenditures
Perceptual
measures
Survey of 201 CEOs listed in the Inc 100 or Inc
500. Answer to several questions in a five-point
Likert scale from “greatly decreased” to “greatly
increased” (over the three-year period):
A. Product/Service design.
B. Packaging design.
C. Advertising design.
D. Store design.
E. Factory design.
F. Office Architecture/Design.
Actual
expenditures
Survey of 800 manufacturing firms (cross
industry) reporting expenditures on seven
categories of design (market research, product
development and improvement, appearance
design, technical design, process/systems
design, engineering design and graphic/brand
design) as a percentage of sales in five levels
(<1%, 1–2.9%, 3–4.9%, 5–9.9%, >10%),
aggregated up to national level estimates.
Black and Baker
1987
Walsh et al.
Dickson et al.
1995
Sentance and
Clark
1997
Measure
Investment in
design
Design activity
Gemser and
Lenders
2001
Industrial
design
intensity
“Objective”
measures
Survey of 27 Dutch manufacturing firms in home
furniture or precision instruments factoranalysing answers to: A. What percentage of
NPD products use design expertise. B. The
number of design awards or prizes. C. The
number of temporarily employed design interns
or design-school students. D. The average
expenditure on product appearance during NPD
projects.
Hertenstein et al.
2001
Design
effectiveness
Perceived
effectiveness
Expert panel ranked 51 firms (cross-industry) by
how “effective” they were in design within each
industry sector
Actual
expenditure
Survey of 637 SMEs in the manufacturing sector
asking questions “How much do you estimate
you spent on design in 2000 in your company?”
With different levels of expenditures (<150 KF
[thousands of French Francs], between 150 KF
and 300 KF, and > 300 KF) and across four
different
categories
(product,
packaging,
graphic, and architectural).
Design France
2002
Investment in
design
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
356 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Reference
Hertenstein et al.
2005
Galindo-Rueda
et al.
2008
Chiva and Alegre
2009
Moultrie and
Livesey
2014
Measure
Industrial
design
effectiveness
Design
investment
Design
investment
Design
spending
Category
Details
Perceived
effectiveness
Expert panel of 138 experts ranked 93
manufacturing firms (nine sectors) on how
“effective” they were, considering factors such
as: Quality of the firm’s design program (e.g.,
number of design awards, peer recognition);
Quality/excellence of design evidenced in the
firm’s products, collateral marketing materials,
etc. (e.g., their opinion of the firm’s design of
products and materials); and importance placed
on the firm’s design program (e.g., large
investment in design).
Actual (estimated)
expenditures
Expenditures estimated at a national (UK) level
based on occupations involved in design and
industries in which design is important, and then
estimating how much was spent in-house vs.
contracted out by extrapolating to the whole
economy
Perceptual
measures
Survey of 182 Italian and Spanish ceramic tile
producers. Answer to question “How much has
your company increased or decreased its
investment in design over the past three years?”
with a seven-point Likert scale ranging from
“greatly decreased” to “greatly increased.”
Actual
expenditures
428 firms answering questions about their total
design expenditures, both in-house and
outsourced, with a “precision estimate” at five
levels (within GBP 1K, 10K, 50K, 100K, and
“can’t estimate”). The total design expenditures
were divided into four categories: Technical
design of products and services; Design of the
user experience for products and services;
Design of promotional materials for specific
products and services; and Design to develop
and promote corporate identity.
Actual expenditures
Several studies have attempted to ask for or estimate the actual amounts spent on, or invested in,
design, and this is the largest category of work related to design inputs. Moultrie and Livesey (2014), for
example, work to develop a framework for the measurement of design investment and to evaluate this
framework in a pilot survey, with the purpose of refining a set of valid measures. They end up performing
a survey in which they asked for both expenditures on design, plus a “precision” of the estimate (how
comfortable the respondent was with his/her estimate of expenditures). Total design expenditures are
divided into four categories: Technical design; User experience design; Graphic design of promotional
materials; and corporate identity design. They carry out their study on a sample of 428 firms, finding that
investment in design is around 4% of turnover (total sales) with 81% of all design investment being in
“technical design,” focused on functionality and performance of new products and services.
Galindo-Rueda et al. (2008) estimate the total expenditure on design in the UK by breaking the
analysis into “outsourced” vs. “in-house” architectural and engineering design services. To do this, they
analyse the industries in which new design might be one of the key objectives. Further, they examine
occupations in which design is mentioned as part of the description of the occupation. When these are
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
357 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
merged, the authors reveal that almost 300,000 employees in the UK are involved in the in-house design
process. Supply-use (input-output) tables are used to estimate the amount of total expenditures on design,
which is estimated at GBP 44 billion in 2004, of which GBP 27 billion could be considered in-house and
17 billion to be “purchased.” Some of this could be considered “investment” in that it could lead to
knowledge-based capital or other intangible assets; the authors estimate this investment to be 50% of total
design spending, although this number is based on surveys of managers and actually is bounded by 9% on
the lower end and 86% on the upper, a very wide range “too wide for comfort.” (Galindo-Rueda et al.,
2008, p. 17)
A few years before that, Sentance and Clark (1997) attempted a similar estimate of national (UK)
design activity but based on a survey of design expenditures in seven different categories as a percentage
of sales in manufacturing companies. The authors estimated that manufacturers spent more on design
(GBP 10 billion) than on R&D (GBP 7 billion) in the prior year, although they acknowledge the lack of
precision in their categorisation scheme. In France, Design France (2002) performed a survey of over 600
small and medium-sized French manufacturers. The respondents were asked to give actual expenditures in
the prior year but rounded into three “bucket” levels: less than 150 000 French Francs (approximately
EUR 23 000), between 150 KF and 300 KF, or greater than 300 000 French Francs (approximately
EUR 46 000). These were further categorised by product, packaging, graphic, and architectural design so
there would be one range for each of the four categories. In the UK, the UK Community Innovation
Survey asked one question on design inputs: what is the firm’s total expenditure on design? Roy and
Potter (1993) surveyed a group of 221 firms in the UK that had taken advantage of a government scheme
to subsidise the hiring of a designer to find out how much the companies had spent in total on the project
and how much they had spent on design so they could estimate the return to design investment.
“Objective” non-pecuniary measures
Objective non-pecuniary measures refer to measures that are not based on actual expenditures, but are
not entirely perceptual, either. We put “objective” into quotes the first time because we understand that
almost all data obtained from people is actually subjective to one degree or another, but here we draw a
distinction between firms reporting numbers and reporting perceptions / agreements with statements. For
example, Gemser and Leenders (2001) measure design activity using a multi-item survey, which they refer
to as “industrial design intensity”—not to be confused with the “intensity” of Moultrie and Livesey (2014),
who refer to the more standard intensity as total expenditures divided by total sales. They ask respondents
as to what percentage of R&D projects professional design expertise was employed; how many design
prizes the firm had won [which is partly an output measure, not an input], the number of temporary design
interns / design school students currently employed at the firm, and the average expenditure devoted to
“product appearance.” Factor analysis revealed that all of the above items loaded onto a single factor that
the authors called “industrial design intensity.”
Perceived effectiveness of design as rated by a third party
This last set of projects is somewhere between inputs and outputs in that design activity is not directly
measured, but rather design performance itself is measured and then correlated with firm performance (see
section 6 below). Hertenstein et al. (2001, 2005) had expert panels evaluate firms on the effectiveness of
their design functions. Herenstein et al. (2001) employed experts to rate firms on their effectiveness and
was able to divide companies into two groups: 26 firms that had more effective design functions and 25
that had less effective design functions. In a similar research design, Hertenstein et al. (2005) was able to
mobilise 138 experts (design managers attending the Design Management Institute conference) to rate
almost 100 firms and sort them into the same two groups as before: effective vs. ineffective design based
on perceived visibility, quality, and investment.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
358 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Sector-specific indicators
There have been numerous studies done on business and innovation practices in some of the designintensive sectors, but there have been relatively few that have been able to come up with sector-specific
indicators that could be used on a large-scale. Even in industries that might be considered design-driven,
such as architecture, clothing and furniture design, or industrial design, there are significant activities such
as marketing, project management, or product implementation that tend to muddle the ability to look at
revenues and outputs directly. In product-oriented and technology-oriented firms, this becomes even more
obscure. Similarly, the advent of web development makes it difficult to see what costs are allocated to a
specific product or service, and which of those costs should be considered development versus
maintenance.
Design experts have indicated that a common notion is to protect IP by way of “thematic design,”
whereby the appearance or form of a product is repeated across the full spectrum of user experience. Thus,
one would expect design elements to be repeated across categories. Since applicants are commonly
allowed to file multiple designs in the same application so long as the designs are all within the same
Locarno class, the practice of thematic design would result in multiple applications by the same applicant
at the same time. One could postulate that such applications would likely fall on the same date for the same
applicant and include at least one application under Locarno class 14, subclass 4. Given that thematic
design has not been widely studied, this may be a fertile area of research. This would allow us to segregate
product-oriented design from pure web-based design.
Measurement of design outputs
Some firms contend that design is the key differentiator permitting them to appropriate value over and
above that of a hypothetical commoditised version of their product. Some of the studies mentioned in the
prior section also attempted to correlate design inputs with different types of outputs, mainly centred on
firm performance. In this section, we review those output measures, grouping them into categories. In
addition to the firm-level analysis, we also discuss the small number of papers that aggregate to a higher
level of analysis.
Table 6.3. Output measures of design at the firm level (Authors’ compilation)
Reference
Measure
Category
Details
Black and Baker
1987
Sales growth
rate
Self-reported
objective financial
information
Companies’ sales growth (four-year average
from 1982–1985) was obtained via interviews
and cross-checked against published figures
Return on assets, profit margin, sales growth.
Profit margin
Perceived
performance; Selfreported objective
financial
information;
Walsh et al.
1992
Roy and Potter
1993
Dickson et al.
1995
Commercial
success
Importance
Perceived
performance
Whether the company produced a new or
redesigned product; whether the company
produced new packaging or graphics, sales,
profit margins on all projects; whether there were
indirect benefits such as learning to manage
designers better; as asked in a survey.
Perceived
performance
Perceptual questions on the importance of
design knowledge for current employees, for
future
MBA
students,
and
for
the
competitiveness of US firms, as answered in a
survey.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
359 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Reference
Measure
Gemser
and
Leenders
2001
Company
performance
Perceived
performance
Perceived performance relative to competitors on
a five-point scale from lowest 20% to top 20% in
quintiles for profit, profit growth, and sales
growth, as asked on a questionnaire.
Hertenstein et al.
2001
Financial
performance
Self-reported
objective financial
information;
Market-based
financial
performance
measures
Financial data from COMPUSTAT and SEC
filings for all 51 companies from 1995-1999,
including cash flow relative to sales and assets;
income relative to sales and assets; growth in
sales, income, and cash flow; and total stock
market value relative to the S&P 500.
Design France
2002
Return
on
investment
Perceived
performance
How long it would take to recoup the investment
in design (perceived), as asked in a survey.
Design Council
2005
Stock
market
performance
Market-based
financial
performance
measures
Total stock market performance for the 61 firms
in the “design index” firms in absolute terms and
relative to the FTSE (UK broad index) from
1995–2004, inclusive.
Corporate
financial
performance
Self-reported
objective financial
information;
Market-based
financial
performance
measures
Financial data from COMPUSTAT and SEC
filings for all 51 companies from 1995-2001,
including cash flow relative to sales and assets;
income relative to sales and assets; growth in
sales, income, and cash flow; and total stock
market value relative to the S&P 500.
Firm
performance
Perceived
performance
Respondents were asked to rate their company’s
performance in a survey, on a seven-point scale
in which 1 was the lowest relative
competitiveness, and 7 was the most
competitive.
Protecting
IP; Success
Design intellectual
property;
Perceived
performance
Use of different forms of IP to protect designs;
Perceptions on achieving business objectives via
design; perceptions on the link between design
and profitability; perceptions on the importance
for the country as a whole; as answered in a
questionnaire in the UK.
Hertenstein et al.
2005
Chiva and Alegre
2009
Design Council
2009
Category
Details
Benefits to the firm
In this section, we review the literature on firm performance as it has been related to various forms of
investment or activity in design. The articles are mainly the same ones discussed in the prior section on
measuring design inputs in the cases (majority) in which the articles were concerned with the performance
implications of design activity and not just measuring design investment in a vacuum. We categorise the
benefits to firms in terms of “objective” vs. subjective data, and within objective, whether the data are
provided directly by the managers, or whether filtered through external evaluations. (As mentioned above,
we put “objective” into quotes the first time round.) Most of the research on design in this area involves
classifying firms into high vs. low design groups and then comparing performance information between the
two groups. Thus it is difficult to assess causality, as several of the authors admit.
Self-reported objective financial information
One of the most common measurements undertaken by researchers has been objective firm
performance data, sometimes solicited directly from managers responding to surveys, and other times via
archival studies (which are often based on surveys). Design orientation of firms was examined by Black
and Baker (1987), who use the company sales growth rate as measure of success, stating that successful
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
360 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
companies have greater design involvement within the NPD process and consider design as a source of
competitive advantage. Firms were classified into three groups: high, medium, and low average sales
growth over the prior four years. These three groups were compared and contrasted along several
perceptual dimensions as discussed in Section 5 above. There are not many obvious differences between
the three groups in terms of design orientation, except in the following cases: when marketing personnel
are involved in the prototype evaluation stage; when engineering design personnel are involved in the
design stage; and pretty much any time aesthetic design personnel were involved in any of the five stages.
In fact, most companies did not have an aesthetic design function and the ones that did tended to be in the
high growth category of firm. The authors conclude that aesthetic design’s involvement in the NPD
process can be highly advantageous for firms.
Hertenstein et al. (2001) find that the more effective design companies as defined above in Section
5.1.5 enjoy better financial performance, which includes standard financial ratios, higher returns on sales,
returns on assets, sales growth, net income, and cash flow, along with stock market value (see below). The
authors divide the 51 companies into two groups of firms: those perceived by a panel of experts to have
highly effective design activity and those perceived to have less effective design activity. Based on the
financial measures mentioned above, the authors propose that firms that have effective industrial design
may earn positive returns on investment in industrial design.
Design intellectual property
Given the many forms that designs take, it is often difficult to unbundle design from innovation and
invention. Registered designs and similar forms of design-related IP provide us with some ability to
measure design. The Design Council (2009) found that 85% of UK businesses felt that design was a
significant part of their business model, but 66% of respondents took no measures to protect their
intellectual property, design or otherwise. Only four per cent of respondents used registered designs, while
another four per cent used unregistered designs. Working under the presumption that those firms using
design protections are a subset of the businesses that consider design important, we can conclude that just
over 90% of them do not use formal design protection measures. In the above-mentioned study, the use of
copyright and trademark protection utilisation far outstrips that of design protection (at 26% and 12%,
respectively: see Section 4 above on bundling); however, those mechanisms may not be used exclusively
by design-exposed firms and thus are more uncertain indicators of design. More firms, on the other hand,
used formal design IP protection than used patents (3%) in the Design Council study. The ratio of usage
provides an interesting clue to the assessment of participation in the design IP realm, given that the United
Kingdom allows for unregistered designs. One could extrapolate that, in those countries where there is not
an option of an unregistered design mechanism, the credible number of bona fide design IP holders may be
at least twice the number reflected by actual holders of design IP. These data, however, do not identify the
quantity of design IP held, only the participation rate within a sample population.
Market-based financial performance measures
Market-based financial performance measures are based on third party assessments of company
performance. Stock market performance, or market value, or the related Tobin’s q, are common measures
used in business research. Tobin’s q is a measure of the value of a firm expressed as the ratio of its
knowledge based capital over the replacement cost of its tangible assets. Knowledge based capital (KBC)
relates to the perceived value of the firm as judged by the price represented in the stock market while the
replacement cost could also be seen as the cash value of all assets and liabilities held by the firm
(Villalonga, 2004). From an empirical point of view, Tobin’s q functions as a good proxy for the KBC of
firms because of the accounting treatment of KBCs (Gu and Lev, 2001). Lindenberg and Ross (1981) find
that the Tobin’s q of firms in R&D- or advertising-intensive industries are abnormally high. This would
indicate that some part of the market value is driven by the added element of intellectual property. It is,
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
361 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
therefore, not uncommon in studies using Tobin’s q as a performance indicator to “adjust” the denominator
to account for the presence of “tangible” KBC (Hall, 1993, Villalonga, 2004).
Relating these measures to outcomes in the design literature, in a study by the UK Design Council
(2005), companies that were “effective users of design” outperformed the UK stock market (FTSE 500
index) by more than 200% between 1994 and 2004. The study selected companies for inclusion in the
“design index” primarily based on their being nominated for and winning design-related awards, such as
Design Effectiveness Awards, D&AD Awards, Interbrand, Millennium Products, and Panel Nominations.
The study concluded that companies that focused on product design not only substantially outperformed
their competitors during good economic times, they also fared significantly better (in terms of stock market
performance) during economic downturns and recovered market share more quickly.
Hertenstein et al. (2005) confirmed “good industrial design is related to corporate financial
performance and stock market performance even after considering expenditures on industrial design.” The
methodology is similar to Hertenstein et al. (2001) with more experts and hence more firms rated on “good
industrial design.” The authors find that stock market returns relative to the S&P 500 index are higher for
the firms rated as having good industrial design, and all other financial measures follow suit in terms of a
positive association between good industrial design and financial performance when looking at the
aggregate seven-year window. In other words, “design pays for itself” (Wong, 2009).
Perceived performance
Gemser and Leenders (2014) find that there is a positive association between industrial design
intensity and firm performance. To measure business performance, they asked managers to rate their firm’s
performance over the prior three year period and score their firms’ profit, profit growth, and sales growth
in quintiles relative to competitors. Then to explore the perceived value of industrial design investments,
the managers involved rated the impact of industrial design investments on specific product performance
measures, and as a result, they found higher benefits of industrial design investments for companies that
invest considerably in it than companies investing little in industrial design. The authors state that company
performance is positively related to industrial design intensity, and the impact of design investments on
company performance is more considerable in precision instrument firms where the strategy of investing in
design is emerging, rather than in the furniture industry where this strategy is quite mature. However, they
find positive associations in both sectors. Dickson et al. (1995) provide descriptive statistics of Inc.
100/500 CEOs’ perceptions about the importance of design. 49% of the CEOs assert that it is important
that all managers be knowledgeable about design, and 46% think that it would be important for MBA
students to study design. Furthermore, 43% of the CEOs disagree with the statement that managers in
general have enough design knowledge to make design decisions.
Walsh et al. (1992) find a positive relationship between design consciousness and perceived success
in firms along several performance dimensions. The 100 firms were divided into two categories, those
more vs. less “design conscious” as described above in Section 5. Across both industry sectors studied,
return on assets was higher in the design conscious group. Sales growth and profit margin had more mixed
results with design consciousness associated with higher performance in one of the two industry sectors.
Chiva and Alegre (2009), in a survey of ceramic tile producers in Spain and Italy, demonstrate an
association between design investment and firm performance, where firm performance is a perceptual
measure based on the performance of the firm relative to competitors. The authors also discuss the
mediating role of “design management” as defined by Dickson et al. (1995) and discussed in Section 5
above. The authors interpret the results as indicating that higher design investments lead to better design
management skills, which then lead to higher firm performance. This interpretation could be the basis for
a link between design and competitive advantage.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
362 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Roy and Potter (1993) collected costs, sales, and profit data, along with whether the firm produced
anything new or redesigned products in a survey of 221 companies that were able to take advantage of a
government scheme to receive some design help in their projects. They were able to reconstruct the
profitability of each of the projects to examine the returns on design investment, and find that 50% of the
projects could be considered a “complete success” given that they were profitable and that there were some
indirect benefits, such as managers learning how to manage the design function better. 10% were
commercially successful but had fewer indirect benefits. And 21% were break even or had small losses,
but exhibited indirect benefits. The authors conclude that inexperienced SME manufacturers can benefit
from professional design help.
The Design Council (2009) study mentioned above also asked respondents whether they believed that
design helps achieve business objectives, and 23% of respondents felt that it contributed “a lot more” than
in the past. Respondents were also asked whether they felt there was a link between design and
profitability, and 59% of respondents agreed with that in contrast with 13% who disagreed. Design France
(2002) asked respondents how long it would take to pay back their investments in design. Recall from
Section 5 above that there were four categories of design: product, packaging, graphic, and architectural
(interior). Respectively, respondents said that it would take less than one year 24%, 29%, 31%, and 27%
of the time for the different categories. For 1-2 years, the percentages were: 38%, 39%, 33%, and 25%
respectively. Thus the modal payback times were: for products, more than one year; for packaging,
1-2 years; for graphic, more than two years; and for architectural, more than two years.
Benefits to the country/region
In contrast with the input measures, which have seen work at multiple levels of analysis, including the
national level, output measures in terms of benefits at the national level have been less studied, other than
asserting that as it appears to be useful for firms to undertake design investment, it must aggregate up to
higher levels of analysis. Some authors find design to be increasingly important for national
competiveness in the global economy (Hargreaves, 2011, Hertenstein et al., 2005, Monseau, 2012,
Moultrie and Livesey, 2014). Governments, particularly in Europe and Asia, as well as some corporations
(Wong, 2009), are becoming considerably more aware of the effects of design on market performance.
Although comparable data on national design industries are relatively hard to collect, making reliable
comparisons between nations difficult, several studies have linked business success to the use of design
(Hertenstein et al., 2005), as discussed above. Further, the Design Council (2009) study asked respondents
(representing firms) in the UK whether they thought that design was “integral to the country’s future
economic performance,” and 52% of respondents agreed with that statement (71% of manufacturers),
whereas only 16% disagreed with it. Likewise, Dickson et al. (1995) asked similar questions with a US
sample and 71% of Inc. 100/500 CEOs agreed that “design issues will be of increasing importance for U.S.
firms’ competitiveness in the coming decades.”
De Rassenfosse (2013) investigated the information content of investment in brand equity and design.
He finds that carrying out an analysis on an unbalanced panel of 32 countries (from 1980 to 2010), brand
equity investment is a powerful predictor of trademark applications, but he found a weak relationship
between investment in architectural and engineering design activities and the demand for design rights.
Two different interpretations were proposed: the first is that the use of design rights is an inappropriate
measure of design activity; the second is that the investment series fail to capture design activity, because
no effect on the demand for design rights was observed. De Rassenfosse concludes, “While registered
design rights may not be a perfect indicator of design activity, they capture one important dimension of
design assets, namely assets with higher-than-average market value.” (de Rassenfosse, 2013, p. 18).
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
363 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Conclusion
Design is a complex activity that touches on many parts of a commercial endeavour. It has proven
difficult to measure and assess precisely because it touches on so many areas of the organisation:
aesthetics, engineering, product development, marketing, advertising, and so on. In this document, we
explored the nature of design, with a focus on industrial design, and examined how firms in nine different
countries protect their design intellectual property. We related designs to traditional forms of intellectual
property and discussed the role and origin of the registered design as another tool in the toolbox of
management. Certain sectors are more popular than others for registered designs, and we reviewed the
most popular classification sectors and noted how they vary from country to country, from ICTs in Korea
and Japan to furnishings / household goods in several European countries. We also brought forward
several other commonalities and differences between the IP regimes for design in the sample countries.
We also discussed bundling design with non-IP complements and why some firms would want to pursue
such strategies.
In the next part of the report, we reviewed trends in design IP, mainly in registered designs, but also in
3D trademarks. Over the last ten years, there has been a steady upward trend in registered designs, but
there are plenty of fluctuations from year to year as old design protections expire and new ones enter the
system via new applications. One gets the impression that design protection is making a steady march
toward wider adoption and diffusion.
In truth, the measurement of design remains an elusive goal, given the difficult-to-define nature of the
elements of design, both as to what constitutes design input as well as what portion of a final product’s
value can and should be attributable to industrial design. Thus the last two sections of the report were
devoted to how design inputs and outputs are manifested in the literature. We began with different studies’
measurement of design investment or design activity. There has been no consensus in the literature, with
researchers doing everything from requesting specific figures for the amount spent on design, to perceptual
measures of design efforts within the firm, to expert ratings of firm efforts. We also examined the output
side of the equation, mainly referring to firm-level benefits listed in the body of literature we reviewed, and
here the dominance of perceptual firm performance measures is quite striking. We noted in the report that
the most popular research design to assess the impact on design first categorises companies into high vs.
low design activity, and then correlates these groups cross-sectionally with perceived performance
benefits. While this work was necessary to lay the groundwork and stimulate interest in the subject, it is
clear that the causality and identification issues need to be tackled in future research.
In addition to future work with new research methodologies, we may find, on the other hand, that this
is a field prime for the application of fuzzy logic, where approximate ranges of values can be integrated
into analyses of very large samples to derive estimates with large standard errors at the firm-level, but
more robust estimates at the industry, regional, or national level. Certainly, aggregation to higher levels of
analysis is another open challenge for design scholars. In any case, there is abundant work for academics,
managers, and policy-makers to do in understanding this exciting topic.
ENQUIRIES INTO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY'S ECONOMIC IMPACT © OECD 2015
364 | DESIGN AND DESIGN FRAMEWORKS: INVESTMENT IN KBC AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
NOTES
271
There are also unregistered designs which afford some protection but whose terms are shorter. In this
report, we will focus on the registered designs.
272
Created in 1967, WIPO is one of the specialised agencies of the United Nations and its mission is to lead
the development of a balanced and effective international intellectual property (IP) system that enables
innovation and creativity for the benefit of all mem