TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS
Transcription
TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS
JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY VOLUME XVIII 2009 No. 1 CONTENTS Symposium USING GOVERNMENT POLICY TO CREATE MIDDLE CLASS GREEN CONSTRUCTION CAREERS Benjamin S. Beach, J.D. ................................................................................... 1 RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY: RENTAL STABILITY ALTERNATIVE Arlo Chase, J.D.............................................................................................. 61 TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS: RACIALIZED CONSUMER FRAUD & REVERSE REDLINING Linda E. Fisher, J.D. .................................................................................... 121 COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS AND COMPREHENSIVE PLANNING: BALANCING COMMUNITY EMPOWERMENT AND THE POLICE POWER Patricia E. Salkin, J.D. and Amy Lavine, J.D. ............................................... 157 THE FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC AND THE FUTURE OF GOVERNMENT SUPPORT FOR THE HOUSING FINANCE SYSTEM Thomas H. Stanton, J.D................................................................................ 217 ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION IN THE SUBPRIME MORTGAGE MARKET: PROPOSALS FOR FAIR LENDING REFORM Winnie F. Taylor, J.D. .................................................................................. 263 Article JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY FELLOW-FEELING AND GENDER IN THE LAW OF PERSONAL INJURY Anita Bernstein, J.D. .................................................................................... 295 Notes and Comments MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO THE EXPANDING TERRY STOP Daniel C. Isaacs........................................................................................... 383 HOW STREAMING AUDIO AND VIDEO CHANGE THE PLAYING FIELD FOR COPYRIGHT CLAIMS Melissa L. Morris......................................................................................... 419 LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS: HOW ANTI-IMMIGRATION SENTIMENT LED TO UNCONSTITUTIONAL LEGISLATION AND THE EROSION OF FUNDAMENTAL PRINCIPLES OF AMERICAN GOVERNMENT Jamie Nielsen............................................................................................... 459 ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK: HOW MANDATING THE HUMAN PAPILLOMAVIRUS VACCINE WILL INCREASE THE USE OF VACCINE EXEMPTIONS AND NEGATIVELY IMPACT OUR NATION’S HEALTH Katharine Southard ...................................................................................... 503 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY TO CREATE MIDDLE CLASS GREEN CONSTRUCTION CAREERS Benjamin S. Beach* INTRODUCTION In the last several years, investment has flowed at significant scale into what has come to be called the “green economy.”1 In particular, the development sector, which encompasses construction and rehabilitation of commercial, residential and other facilities and infrastructure, has embraced “green” in its materials, processes and products.2 At the same time, federal, * Staff Attorney, Community Benefits Law Center. The author would like to thank Scott Cummings, Evan Denerstein, Joanna Lee, Julian Gross and Adrian Martinez for comments on drafts and helpful conversations. 1 Joel Makower et al., The State of Green Business 2009, GREENER WORLD MEDIA, Feb. 2009, at 28. Venture capital investment in green technologies soared to a record $7.6 billion, double the previous year, according to Greentech Media. Defining the “green economy” is beyond the scope of this article, which focuses specifically on green building and construction. A number of interesting, accessible articles have addressed the question of what constitutes a “green job,” including: Bryan Walsh, What Is a Green Collar Job, Exactly?, TIME, May 26, 2008, available at http://www.time.com/time/ health/article/0,8599,1809506,00.html, and Raquel Pinderhughes, Green Collar Jobs, CITY OF BERKELEY, OFF. OF ENERGY & SUSTAINABLE DEV. (2007), available at http://www.michigan.gov/documents/nwlb/Green_Collar _Jos_236013_7.pdf. 2 Makower, supra note 1, at 22. The number of Energy Star-certified buildings has increased from 90 buildings certified in 1999 to more than 3,200 in 2008. In 2009 alone, that number grew 230 percent, more than doubling from the 1,400 buildings that certified in 2007. For the last several years, the growth in certified projects in LEED for New Construction, LEED 1 BEACHFINAL.DOC 2 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY state and local governments have entered the green development sector as funders, developers and regulators.3 Indeed, in 2009, billions of dollars flowed from public coffers to fund “green” development projects.4 This sudden and massive influx of funds should prompt stakeholders at every level to consider what policies will govern the expenditure of such funds, and what goals will be served by such policies. Supporters have rightly justified government facilitation of green development on environmental grounds.5 But increasingly, in advancing arguments for this government activity, proponents, including the Obama administration, have focused on that most meaningful of economic benefits: jobs.6 Community-based and labor organizations around the country for Existing Buildings, and LEED for Commercial Interiors, has enjoyed an annual growth rate of anywhere from 10 to 90 percent. 3 According to the U.S. Green Building Council’s website, “various LEED initiatives including legislation, executive orders, resolutions, ordinances, policies, and initiatives are found in 43 states, including 190 localities (126 cities, 36 counties, and 28 towns), 36 state governments (including the Commonwealth of Puerto Rico), 12 federal agencies or departments, 16 public school jurisdictions, and 39 institutions of higher education across the United States.” U.S. GREEN BUILDING COUNCIL: GOVERNMENT RESOURCES (2009), http://www.usgbc.org/DisplayPage.aspx? CMSPageID=1779 [hereinafter USGBC Website]. 4 U.S. Green Building Council, Select Highlights of Provisions Relevant to Green Building in the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, https://www.usgbc.org/ShowFile.aspx?DocumentID=5458. According to the U.S. Green Building Council’s website, the federal government has 2,831 projects pursuing LEED certification, state governments have 1,890 projects pursuing LEED certification and local governments have 2889 projects pursuing LEED certification. USGBA Website, supra note 3. 5 U.S Envtl. Protection Agency, Why Build Green, http://www.epa.gov/ greenbuilding/pubs/whybuild.htm (last visited Dec. 1, 2009). 6 Joseph R. Biden, Green Jobs Are a Way to Aid the Middle Class, PHILADELPHIA ENQUIRER, Feb. 27, 2009; Reuters, More Green Building and Energy Efficiency Could Save U.S. Economy $1.2 Trillion, REUTERS, July 30, 2009, available at http://www.reuters.com/article/pressRelease/idUS242898 +30-Jul-2009+BW20090730 (stating that a targeted investment in green building of $50 billion a year for a 10-year period could create as many as 900,000 jobs). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 3 have for some time observed a significant gap between the jobrelated promises that attend government-facilitated development and the reality of low-road construction work with negligible opportunities for low-income communities and communities of color.7 In addition, environmental justice groups have long exposed the fact that these same communities tend to experience most severely the very environmental harms that green development aims to address.8 A number of these organizations have come together to successfully advocate for local, state and federal policy that addresses these concerns and treats a career in green construction as a pathway out of poverty.9 Much of this work builds off a “Construction Careers” model pioneered in Los Angeles and Oakland10 that advances the values of job quality 7 See, e.g., Kate Davis et al., Subsidizing the Low Road: Economic Development in Baltimore, GOOD JOBS FIRST (2002), available at http://www.goodjobsfirst.org/pdf/balt.pdf; Greg LeRoy et al., Economic Development in Minnesota: High Subsidies, Low Wages, Absent Standards, GOOD JOBS FIRST (1999), available at http://www.goodjobsfirst.org/pdf /mngjf.pdf; Los Angeles Alliance for a New Economy, Who Benefits from Redevelopment in Los Angeles?, http://74.10.59.52/laane/docs/research/Who Benefits_es.pdf. 8 Nancy D. Perkins, Livability, Regional Equity and Capability: Closing In on Sustainable Land Use, 37 U. BALT. L. REV 157, 157 (2008) (“Deeper reforms are now being encouraged, due in part to the persistence of environmental justice advocates, whose calls for fairness in the distribution of environmental burdens and benefits have begun to infiltrate land use decisionmaking.”). 9 Michael Burnham, Jobs at Issue as Labor-Enviro Coalitions Stump for Climate Bill, N.Y. TIMES, Apr. 16, 2009, available at http://www.nytimes. com/gwire/2009/04/16/16greenwire-jobs-at-issue-as-laborenviro-coalitionsstump-10548.html; Leo Gerard & Michael Peck, Op-Ed., Green Jobs, Good Jobs: Business, Labor and Government are Working Together to Revitalize Pennsylvania, PITTSBURGH POST-GAZETTE, Mar. 25, 2009, available at http://www.post-gazette.com/pg/09084/957972-109.stm; LA Passes Ordinance for Green Building Retrofits, SUSTAINABLEBUSINESS.COM, Apr. 14, 2009, available at http://www.sustainablebusiness.com/index.cfm/go/ news.display/id/17995. 10 See infra Section III; see also Ronald D. White, Program Would Help At-Risk L.A. Residents Get Construction Jobs, L.A. TIMES, Sept. 1, 2008, at BEACHFINAL.DOC 4 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY and equitable access in the construction sector, and which itself is an example of the growing movement of localized advances in organizing successful campaigns for policy change led by community-labor coalitions11 As described below, this model has shown favorable results for facilitating the movement of individuals from low-income communities into sustained careers in the construction sector. The objective of this article is to point the way toward policy that meaningfully and lawfully addresses the important concerns with green development and results in middle class careers in green construction for all segments of a community. Part I examines the green development sector’s salient features, with particular focus on jobs, workforce development and environmental justice. Part II describes and analyzes the government’s role in that sector and its responsiveness to the issues explored in Part I. Part III proposes a model “Green Construction Careers” policy based on examples brought about by the advocacy of coalitions containing community, labor and environmental organizations. This model centers on a career pipeline that starts with community-based outreach and intake, includes high-quality training and concludes with entry into a construction trades union. Part IV examines some of the numerous and significant legal considerations that arise in connection with the adoption and/or application of such policy. In particular, measures relating to labor standards, apprenticeship and targeted hiring each give rise to a constellation of issues under the Federal Constitution and Federal statutes. However, with appropriate findings and careful drafting, policymakers may readily avoid legal obstacles to C1, available at http://articles.latimes.com/2008/sep/01/business/fiapprentice1. 11 See Scott Cummings & Steven A. Boutcher, Mobilizing Government Law for Low-Wage Workers, U. CHI. LEGAL F. (Forthcoming); Peter Dreier, Good Jobs, Healthy Cities, AMERICAN PROSPECT, Sept. 21, 2009, available at http://www.prospect.org/cs/articles?article=good_jobs_healthy_city; Benjamin I. Sachs, Labor Law Renewal, 1 HARV. L. & POL. REV. 375 (2007); Richard Schragger, Mobile Capital, Local Economic Regulation and the Democratic City, 123 HARV. L. REV. at 29–39 (F 2009). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 5 meaningful, effective policy. I. THE GREEN DEVELOPMENT SECTOR For purposes of this article, “green development” means construction, rehabilitation or retrofitting of commercial, residential and other facilities and infrastructure for the purposes of improving the environmental impact thereof. This definition is thus focused particularly on green building, which the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) has defined as “the practice of creating structures and using processes that are environmentally responsible and resource-efficient throughout a building’s life-cycle from siting to design, construction, 12 operation, maintenance, renovation and deconstruction.” Expanding on this definition, the EPA explains that “green buildings are designed to reduce the overall impact of the built environment on human health and the natural environment” by: (a) efficiently using energy, water, and other resources; (b) protecting occupant health and improving employee productivity; and (c) reducing waste, pollution and environmental degradation.13 While there is vigorous debate about whether certain kinds of projects should be called “green” due to their net environmental impact, there is little doubt as to the overall environmental value of green development. In the U.S., commercial and residential building operations account for about 40 percent of the primary energy consumption, 20 to 25 percent of the landfill waste and 5 to 12 percent of the water 14 consumption. A number of credible studies demonstrate that green buildings substantially reduce energy use, carbon 12 U.S. Envtl. Protection Agency, Basic Information, Definition of Green Building, http://www.epa.gov/greenbuilding/pubs/about.htm#1 (last visited Dec. 1, 2009). 13 Id. 14 SECRETARIAT OF THE COMMISSION FOR ENVTL. COOPERATION, GREEN BUILDINGS IN NORTH AMERICA: OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES 4 (2008), available at http://www.cec.org/files/PDF//GB_Report_EN.pdf. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 6 emissions and water use, and generate significant waste cost savings. 15 In addition, green buildings have been found to contribute to the health and productivity of their occupants.16 Investments in the green development sector also appear to offer notable returns in the area of job creation. One recent study concluded that green-building retrofits would generate 7 direct jobs and 4.9 indirect jobs for every $1 million in expenditure, vastly outpacing the job-creating capacity of comparable investment in oil and gas.17 Another study modeled a hypothetical scenario in which green building measures were undertaken in an amount sufficient to reduce energy 15 See, e.g., CATHY TURNER ET AL., NEW BUILDINGS INSTITUTE, ENERGY PERFORMANCE OF LEED FOR NEW CONSTRUCTION BUILDINGS 5 (2008), available at http://newbuildings.org/sites/default/files/Energy_ Performance_of_LEED-NC_Buildings-Final_3-4-08b.pdf (stating that LEEDNC Certified buildings deliver energy savings of between 25 to 30 percent of the national average); ROB WATSON, GREENER WORLD MEDIA, GREEN BUILDING IMPACT REPORT 10–12 (2008) (finding that LEED Certified green buildings have already produced energy savings equivalent to burning 1.3 million tons of coal for electricity, saved 9.5 billion gallons of water, and reduced CO2 emissions by 7 million tons); GREG KATZ, SUSTAINABLE BUILDING TASK FORCE, THE COSTS AND FINANCIAL BENEFITS OF GREEN BUILDINGS: A REPORT TO CALIFORNIA’S SUSTAINABLE BUILDING TASK FORCE 19, 40, 52 (2003) (finding that green buildings generate 30% energy savings on landscaping and 50–75% waste diversion). 16 See William J. Fisk, Health And Productivity Gains from Better Indoor Environments and Their Relationship with Building Energy Efficiency, 25 ANN. REV. ENERGY ENVTL. 537 (2000); Judith Heerwagen, Green Buildings, Organizational Success, and Occupant Productivity, 28 BLDG. RES. & INFO. 353–367 (2000). 17 ROBERT POLLIN ET AL., POLITICAL ECON. RESEARCH INST. & CTR. FOR AM. PROGRESS, THE ECONOMIC BENEFITS OF INVESTING IN CLEAN ENERGY 28 (2009); see also SARAH WHITE & JASON WALSH, CTR. ON WISCONSIN STRATEGY, GREENER PATHWAYS: JOBS AND WORKFORCE DEVELOPMENT IN THE GREEN ECONOMY 15 (2008) (“Most credible estimates calculate eight to eleven direct jobs per $1 million invested. A 2004 Apollo Alliance paper counted roughly 10 jobs per $1 million invested in highperformance buildings; a forthcoming study by COWS and the University of Florida’s Powell Center for Construction and Environment projects 10 on-site jobs per $1 million invested in a typical owner-occupied residential efficiency retrofit in Wisconsin.”). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 7 consumption levels of American residential and commercial buildings by 35% over 30 years and concluded that the scenario would require nearly 81,000 green jobs, approximately 36,000 in the residential sector and 45,000 in the commercial sector.18 However, from the standpoint of job quality and equitable access, there appears to be little that distinguishes “green” construction from conventional construction.19 This fact gives rise to a fundamental challenge for policymakers seeking to create good jobs for all segments of a community through green development for several reasons. First, the conventional construction sector is very much divided between low road non-union and high road union employers. Data on construction wages indicates a significant wage gap between union and non-union construction workers.20 An Economic Policy Institute analysis of nonunion laborers, carpenters, painters, roofers and other non-licensed trades found that half of the 3.5 million workers in this category earned less than $12.50 an hour and one third earned less than the federal poverty wage for a family of four.21 This is the same group of workers most likely to undertake the energy-efficiency retrofits and/or weatherization projects that, as described below, have received tremendous attention from government entities looking to participate in the green economy.22 18 GLOBAL INSIGHT, U.S. METRO ECONOMIES: CURRENT AND POTENTIAL JOBS IN THE U.S. GREEN ECONOMY 15 (2008) (report prepared for the United States Conference of Mayors and the Mayors Climate Protection Center). 19 Id. (“Many of the workers required to complete the renovation work and installations of efficiency upgrades fall under the classifications of the traditional construction trades that comprise this category. Ultimately, increasing demand for green building work can be expected to generate new employment opportunities for electricians, HVAC technicians, carpenters, plumbers, roofers, laborers, and insulation workers, among others.”); White & Walsh, supra note 17, at 16 (“Jobs in energy efficiency retrofitting look a lot like traditional construction jobs.”). 20 PHILIP MATTERA ET AL., HIGH ROAD OR LOW ROAD: JOB QUALITY IN THE NEW GREEN ECONOMY 5 (Good Jobs First 2009). 21 Id. at 21. 22 Id. at 25 (“In order to meet the President’s stimulus objectives, the residential energy efficiency sector must find ways to train thousands of BEACHFINAL.DOC 8 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY Second, the construction sector is plagued by longestablished underrepresentation of certain demographic groups.23 In particular, African-Americans residing in major metropolitan areas with high concentrations of African-Americans have substantially lower levels of participation in the construction workforce than they have in the general workforce,24 and women make up less than 3% of the construction workforce25. Third, there is a significant need to invest in training a new generation of construction workers. In a recent energy utility sector survey, nearly half of respondents said that more than 20 percent of their work force—mostly skilled tradespeople—would retire within the next five to seven years.26 Providing this training seems plausible: many jobs in the industry require a significant amount of postsecondary education, but not a fouryear degree.27 Yet, the construction training available outside of union apprenticeship programs may often be ill-suited to the task.28 Finally, the complex labyrinth of legal and contractual requirements, customs, practices, entities, politics and interpersonal relationships that characterize the high road workers and raise standards in what is currently a low-wage industry.”). 23 See Jason Parkin, Constructing Meaningful Access to Work: Lessons from the Port of Oakland Project Labor Agreement, 35 COLUM. HUMAN RIGHTS L. REV. 375, 377–383 (discussing history of exclusion of minorities and women from construction sector). 24 TODD SWANSTROM, PUBLIC POLICY RESEARCH CENTER, UNIV. OF MO., ST. LOUIS, THE ROAD TO GOOD JOBS: PATTERNS OF EMPLOYMENT IN THE CONSTRUCTION INDUSTRY 5 (2008). 25 BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS, EMPLOYED PERSONS BY DETAILED OCCUPATION AND SEX, 2008 ANNUAL AVERAGES, available at www.bls.gov/cps/wlf-table11-2009.pdf (indicating that the percentage of women in “Construction and Extraction” occupations is 2.5%). 26 Id. (citing AMERICAN PUBLIC POWER ASSOCIATION, WORKFORCE PLANNING FOR PUBLIC POWER UTILITIES: ENSURING RESOURCES TO MEET PROJECTED NEEDS (2005)). 27 White & Walsh, supra note 17, at 4. 28 See BUSINESS ROUNDTABLE, TRAINING PROBLEMS IN OPEN SHOP CONSTRUCTION: A CONSTRUCTION INDUSTRY COST EFFECTIVENESS PROJECT REPORT 4 (1990). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 9 unionized construction trades can stymie even the most wellintentioned of policies. A new worker must first decide which trade to enter and then obtain admission to the appropriate union apprenticeship29 program.30 Admissions standards and practices (including the frequency of openings) vary across programs, as do the durations of the apprenticeships.31 The actual hiring of an apprentice can be a function of contractor preferences, union hiring hall practices, referral rules, union bylaws, collective bargaining agreements32 and state or federal apprenticeship standards33, among other things. Notably, one tool that has gained use in the construction sector to create uniform standards across a project, and which is discussed below, is the project labor agreement or PLA. This is a comprehensive agreement ensuring labor peace for a 29 An apprentice is a worker new to the construction trades and participating in an “on the job” training program unique to a particular trade or craft. Building and Construction Trades unions operate apprenticeship programs in many jurisdictions, sometimes in conjunction with employers through Joint Apprenticeship Training Councils. 30 Kathleen Mulligan-Hansel, Making Development Work for Local Residents, PARTNERSHIP FOR WORKING FAMILIES, July 2008, at 50. 31 Id. 32 A “collective bargaining agreement” is a contract between an employer and a union representing employees, regarding conditions of employment for a particular bargaining unit; covers wages, hours, benefits, and many other terms and conditions of employment, such as protection from termination of employment without just cause. Collective bargaining agreements usually also establish grievance resolution procedures. 33 Under the Fitzgerald Act-National Apprenticeship Act (29 U.S.C. § 50), the Labor Standards for the Registration of Apprenticeship Programs (29 C.F.R. § 29), and the Equal Employment Opportunity in Apprenticeship regulations (29 C.F.R. § 30), the U.S. Department of Labor’s Office of Apprenticeship establishes basic standards for all apprenticeship programs, including provisions regarding recruitment, selection, and training of apprentices. These laws and regulations establish criteria for registering apprenticeship programs with the federal government in order to “safeguard the welfare of apprentices.” (29 U.S.C. § 50). They also determine how State Apprenticeship Councils (SACs) can be created. SACs must be approved by the federal government and meet certain minimum federal standards. (29 CFR § 29.1). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 10 construction project by establishing ahead of time key terms of hiring procedures and working conditions, generally with reference to terms of local collective bargaining agreements in various trades. Neither contractors nor workers need be unionized in order to work on PLA projects. Public and private entities overseeing large construction projects often require PLAs to be in place in order to avoid costly delays due to labor unrest, to facilitate high-road employment practices, and sometimes to facilitate targeted hiring programs. Critically, where properly drafted, a PLA’s uniform rules for hiring— including targeted hiring—can cut across and supersede the complex labyrinth of rules referred to above that may otherwise govern a project. In addition to the jobs-related challenge, policymakers must also confront an environmental justice34 issue. From the standpoint of environmental justice, it is, ironically, difficult to distinguish green development as currently practiced in the U.S. from conventional development. One community development corporation, or “CDC,” that develops in low-income communities in New York found that available green building subsidy programs “do not include preference, set aside, or other accommodations based on the affordability of the housing to low-income purchasers or tenants or its not-for-profit community-based auspices.”35 Further, the CDC found the particular green building certification process, required by funders, “costly and time consuming, especially for a not-forprofit affordable housing developer operating on a shoestring 36 budget.” At the same time, prevailing “green building” standards are silent as to the siting of green facilities in low34 The term “environmental justice” as used in this article includes the concept that healthy or green buildings should be sited in low-income communities and communities of color, which is a direct corollary of the more traditional meaning of the term associated with concept of the preventing the siting of environmentally harmful uses in such communities. 35 Carmen Huertas-Noble, Jessica Rose & Brian Glick, The Greening of Community Economic Development: Dispatches from New York City, 31 W. NEW ENG. L. REV. 645, 662 (2009). 36 Id. at 663. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 11 income communities or communities with concentrations of negative environmental impacts.37 This combination of obstacles to green development and a lack of proactive policy to encourage such development in disadvantaged communities makes it less likely that green buildings will arise where they are most needed. Thus, as government enters the green development sector, policymakers must either confront or ignore the significant jobs and environmental justice issues discussed above. As the next section explains, they have not yet done so on a scale commensurate with the new investment in green development, and are therefore missing a major opportunity to obtain better social and economic outcomes. II. THE GOVERNMENT ROLE IN GREEN DEVELOPMENT The last several years have witnessed an explosion of government efforts to encourage and participate in green development, and a relative decline in private sector investment.38 Every level of American government has either adopted green building standards or allocated funds to support green development, or both. This vast expansion of the 37 Nancy J. King et. al., Creating Incentives For Sustainable Buildings: A Comparative Law Approach Featuring the United States and the European Union, 23 VA. ENVTL. L.J. 397, 404–405 (2005) (citing Jude L. Fernando et al., Rethinking Sustainable Development: Toward Just Sustainability in Urban Communities, Building Equity Rights with Sustainable Solutions, 590 ANNALS AM. ACAD. POL. & SOC. SCI. 35, 36 (2003)) (contrasting “green building” with “sustainable construction” and noting “many definitions of sustainable construction incorporate progressive social concepts, such as environmental justice, not directly addressed by green building standards. To include environmental justice in sustainable construction is to more fully recognize the social responsibility component of sustainable development. For example, a broad view of sustainable construction would consider the impact of building construction on the equitable distribution of environmental resources, along with other issues of social responsibility”). 38 See Nathaniel Gronewold, Clean Tech Frets as Power of Government’s Purse Grows, GREENWIRE, June 25, 2009, http://www.eenews.net/public/ Greenwire/2009/06/25/11. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 12 government role in green development, of course, heralds a significant opportunity to shape the emerging sector through government policy. Indeed, there is some indication already of the efficacy of such policy: at least one study has found significant correlations between the presence of a municipal green building policy and the number of green buildings per capita.39 A. Green Building Standards Government entities at every level have promoted green development through the adoption of green building standards. Forty-three states have adopted energy-efficiency codes for residential buildings and forty-one have adopted such codes for commercial buildings.40 At the same time, many building codes have been supplemented by green-building rating systems. Two rating systems have dominated the market: the Leadership in Energy and Environmental Design (“LEED”) (from the U.S. 41 Green Building Council (“USGBC”)) and Green Globe. The USBGC indicates that various LEED initiatives including legislation, executive orders, resolutions, ordinances, policies, and initiatives are found in 43 states, including 190 localities, 36 state governments, 12 federal agencies or departments, 16 public school jurisdictions, and 39 institutions of higher education.42 39 Julie Cidell, The Role of Public Policy in Private Sector Decisions to Build Green, INDUSTRY STUDIES ASSOC., May 28, 2009, available at http://www.industrystudies.pitt.edu/chicago09/docs/Cidell%202.3.pdf. 40 David E. Adelman & Kirsten H. Engel, Reorienting State Climate Change Policies to Induce Technological Change, 50 ARIZ. L. REV. 835, 872 (2008). 41 Id. at 873 (“The LEED standards are based on building performance in the following categories: site selection; water efficiency; energy and atmosphere; materials and resources; indoor environmental quality and innovation; and design quality. LEED has been particularly criticized for its vulnerability to manipulation given the broad range of features that count towards obtaining green certification and thus the ease with which a building with mediocre green credentials in its major features might nevertheless obtain a LEED certification.”). 42 USGBC Website, supra note 3. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 13 Unfortunately, the LEED standards are silent with respect to job quality and labor practices.43 As noted, green buildings have been shown to improve the productivity and health of occupying workers.44 Further, LEED standards for Existing Buildings do award points toward certification for the purchase of environmentally sound cleaning products,45 which may create fewer health risks for custodial workers. Yet, nothing on the face of the LEED standards prevents a building from receiving LEED certification, despite its having been constructed by workers receiving low wages, no benefits and poor training. Further, nothing in the LEED standards compels the hiring of local residents for construction jobs, despite the rather obvious potential environmental benefit of reduced emissions associated with worker commutes. In fairness, the LEED standards may well not have been designed to address these issues, which may not fall squarely within the expertise of the U.S.G.B.C. B. Funding Recently, the Federal government has dramatically expanded funding for green construction. According to the Apollo Alliance,46 the American Reinvestment and Recovery Act (“ARRA”), which became law in February 2009, contained approximately $110 billion in funding for the green sector, including $34 billion to improve energy efficiency, $17.7 billion to modernize and expand the transit systems, $7.9 billion to scale up renewable energy development, $10.9 billion to modernize and expand the electric grid, and $29.14 billion on 43 See Mattera, supra note 20, at 21. See generally Fisk, supra note 16. 45 U.S. Green Building Council, LEED for Existing Buildings: Operations and Maintenance Rating System, Sept. 2008, at 77. 46 The Apollo Alliance describes itself as “a coalition of labor, business, environmental, and community leaders working to catalyze a clean energy revolution that will put millions of Americans to work in a new generation of high-quality, green-collar jobs.” See Apollo Alliance, About, www.apollo alliance.org/about (last visited Oct. 12, 2009). 44 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 14 roads and bridges.47 Funds allocated for energy efficiency can reasonably be expected to flow directly into green construction, as more than $20 billion is directed to the construction or rehabilitation of federally-owned or funded buildings.48 In addition, energy efficiency retrofits of residential buildings received a massive boost in the ARRA, which allocated $5 billion to the Department of Energy’s Weatherization Assistance Program (“WAP”).49 The WAP’s purpose is “to increase the energy efficiency of dwellings owned or occupied by lowincome persons, reduce their total residential expenditures, and improve their health and safety.”50 Fortunately, the Federal government has also seen fit to address the issues of job quality and equitable access in connection with these new outlays for green construction. In April 2009, the Office of Management and Budget issued a memorandum to federal departments and agencies setting forth “government-wide guidance for carrying out programs and 47 Elena Foshay & Keith Schneider, Congress Approves Clean Energy Provisions of Stimulus; Consistent With Apollo Economic Recovery Act, Feb. 13, 2009, http://apolloalliance.org/rebuild-america/energy-efficiency-rebuildamerica/data-points-energy-efficiency/clean-energy-provisions-of-stimulus-areconsistent-with-apollo-economic-recovery-act/. 48 Id. ($4.5 billion for renovations and repairs to federal buildings including focused on increasing energy efficiency, $4 billion to HUD for public housing building repair and modernization, including critical safety repairs and energy efficiency upgrades, $2.25 billion for a new program to upgrade HUD sponsored low-income housing to increase energy efficiency, including new insulation, windows, and furnaces, $2.25 billion to the HOME Program to help local communities build and rehabilitate low-income housing using green technologies, $4.23 billion for energy efficiency improvements to Department of Defense and Veterans Administration facilities, $1.45 billion for military hospital construction and energy efficiency improvements, $3.2 billion increase on limitation on Qualified Energy Conservation Bonds (QECBs), which eligibility for QECBs to include green community programs that use loans or repayment mechanisms to support such programs, and $510 million for energy-efficient retrofits for Native American housing). 49 See U.S. DEP’T OF ENERGY, FUNDING OPPORTUNITY ANNOUNCEMENT FOR WEATHERIZATION FORMULA GRANTS 5 (2009). 50 Id. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 15 activities” enacted in ARRA.51 The memorandum, among other things, encouraged agencies to: support entities with “sound track records” of compliance with wage and hour, occupational safety and health, and collective bargaining laws and that “are creating good jobs”; support projects that “seek to ensure that the people who live in the local community get the job opportunities that accompany the investment”; and support projects “that make effective use of community-based organizations in connecting disadvantaged people with economic opportunities.”52 States and localities have also entered the green development sector as funders. Numerous state and local laws provide financial incentives for businesses to adopt green construction or renovation practices.53 States have also established subsidy programs to reduce the cost of residential solar panel installation.54 Local governments have established programs to reduce permit fees or grant property tax exemptions to owners that build LEED-certified green buildings.55 Apart from the examples described below, however, it appears that few states or localities have attached jobs-related standards to these programs. III. THE GREEN CONSTRUCTION CAREERS MODEL The Green Construction Careers Model proposed in this 51 Memorandum from Peter R. Orzag, Dir. Office of Mgmt. and Budget, Updated Implementing Guidance for the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, (Apr. 3, 2009) available at http://www.white house.gov/omb/assets/memoranda_fy2009/m09-15.pdf. 52 Id. at 5–6. 53 King et al., supra note 37, at 418; New Energy for States, Feb. 2006, APOLLO ALLIANCE 15 (describing tax credit programs in New York, Maryland and Oregon for energy efficient buildings). 54 See, e.g., James Hohmann, Subsidies Help Residents Go Solar, WASH. POST, Aug. 14, 2009, at 10; Marc Lifsher, California Solar-Power Subsidy Program Approaches Its Limit, L.A. TIMES, July 6, 2009, at B1. 55 Adelman & Engel, supra note 40, at 873–874; Tanya Batallas, N.J. Small Businesses Losing Out as State Supports Larger Solar Ventures, NEW JERSEY STAR-LEDGER, Aug. 27, 2009. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 16 article offers an important tool for advancing the values of job quality, equitable access and environmental justice in the green development sector. It aims to have substantial numbers of formerly disadvantaged workers solidly advancing in sustained high-road careers in green construction. It operates by ensuring high-quality training and employment for these workers, cutting through legal and bureaucratic obstacles, and bringing sometimes divided constituencies together in collaborative working relationships. The model derives much of its content from the Construction Careers model pioneered in Los Angeles and Oakland by community and labor organizations, construction employers and local officials.56 This model couples specific measures that facilitate the hiring of targeted workers with the use of project labor agreements that ensure job quality and labor peace. There are several examples of the Construction Careers model now at work. The Los Angeles Unified School District (“LAUSD”) established a targeted hiring program for its $19 billion school site modernization and construction program via a Project Stabilization Agreement, which established a goal that 50% of the construction workforce consist of workers residing within the district.57A 2008 study by the University of California at Los Angeles determined that LAUSD’s program resulted in targeted workers comprising 41% of apprentices, 39% of journey-level workers,58 and 23% of foremen on LAUSD 56 Cummings & Boutcher, supra note 11, at 22. For more information on the Construction Careers model, see generally Kathleen Mulligan-Hansel, Making Development Work for Local Residents, PARTERNSHIP FOR WORKING FAMILIES (2008). 57 LOS ANGELES UNIFIED SCH. DIST. PROJECT STABILIZATION AGREEMENT—NEW CONSTRUCTION AND MAJOR REHABILITATION FUNDED BY PROPOSITION BB AND/OR MEASURE K §3.5 (May 12, 2003), available at http://www.laschools.org/contractor/fca/fs-fca/download/psa/documents/ Project_Stabilization_Agreement.pdf. 58 A journey-level worker is an individual who has completed an apprenticeship in the construction trades and is therefore eligible for certain wages, benefits and seniority on construction jobs. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 17 projects.59The Los Angeles Department of Public Works has negotiated a number of Project Labor Agreements for major projects that include a goal that 30-40% of the construction workforce consists of targeted workers.60 As of June 2009, targeted workers made up between 19 and 35% of the respective workforces on these projects.61 The Port of Oakland, California established a targeted hiring program for its $1.2 billion modernization via a Project Labor Agreement that set a goal that 50% of work hours be performed by residents of a designated local impact area.62 The PLA also set a goal that 20% of all construction work be performed by apprentice-level workers, all of whom should reside in the local 59 Memorandum from Veronica Soto, Dir. Of Contractor Relations & Small Bus., to Ramon Cortines, Superintendent of the Los Angeles Unified Sch. Dist. Facilities (Jan. 28, 2009), available at http://www.laschoolboard. org/files/14.%20We%20Build%20Annual%20Report.pdf. 60 CITY OF LOS ANGELES DEP’T OF PUBLIC WORKS, BUREAU OF ENGINEERING, PROJECT LABOR AGREEMENT FOR FIRE STATION NO. 64— SOUTH LOS ANGELES § 7.6, available at http://bca.lacity.org/site/pdf/hiring/ Fire%20Station%2064%20PLA.pdf; CITY OF LOS ANGELES DEP’T OF PUBLIC WORKS, BUREAU OF ENGINEERING, PROJECT LABOR AGREEMENT FOR AVENUE 45 & ARROYO DR. RELIEF SEWER § 7.6, available at http://bca. lacity.org/site/pdf/hiring/Avenue%2045%20pla.pdf; CITY OF LOS ANGELES DEP’T OF PUBLIC WORKS, BUREAU OF ENGINEERING PROJECT LABOR AGREEMENT FOR POLICE ADMINISTRATION BUILDING § 7.6, available at http://bca.lacity.org/site/pdf/hiring/PAB%20Signed%20PLA.pdf. 61 LOS ANGELES DEP’T OF PUBLIC WORKS, OFFICE OF CONTRACT COMPLIANCE, BUREAU OF CONTRACT ADMIN., FIRE STATION #64: SUMMARY OF LOCAL HIRING @ 99% COMPLETION, available at http://bca.lacity.org/ site/pdf/hiring/PLA%20Fire%20Station%2064.pdf; LOS ANGELES DEP’T OF PUBLIC WORKS, OFFICE OF CONTRACT COMPLIANCE, BUREAU OF CONTRACT ADMIN., AVENUE 45 & ARROYO DR. RELIEF SEWER: SUMMARY OF LOCAL HIRING AT @ 53% COMPLETION, available at http://bca.lacity.org/site/pdf/ hiring/PLA%20Avenue%2045.pdf; LOS ANGELES DEP’T OF PUBLIC WORKS, OFFICE OF CONTRACT COMPLIANCE, BUREAU OF CONTRACT ADMINISTRATION, POLICE ADMINISTRATION BUILDING, SUMMARY OF LOCAL HIRING AT @ 99% COMPLETION, available at http://bca.lacity.org/site/pdf/ hiring/PLA%20PHQ.pdf. 62 PORT OF OAKLAND MARITIME & AVIATION PROJECT LABOR AGREEMENT, Art. V, § 6, available at http://www.communitybenefits.org/ downloads/Project%20Labor%20Agreement.pdf. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 18 impact area.63 Between 2001 and 2007, the program resulted in 31% of targeted worker hours having been performed by these targeted workers.64 The Community Redevelopment Agency of the City of Los Angeles has also adopted a Construction Careers and Project Stabilization policy for construction projects that it undertakes and subsidizes.65 This policy requires that developers or prime contractors on major projects undertaken or subsidized by the agency reserve 30% of construction work hours for local residents, 10% of construction work hours for local, low-income or otherwise disadvantaged residents, and 50% of apprentice work hours for local residents.66 The policy further requires contractors and subcontractors to become signatory to a master Project Labor Agreement negotiated between the construction trades unions and the agency that contains a set of targeted 67 hiring measures. The policy also calls on developers and prime contractors to submit a targeted hiring schedule that establishes the approximate hiring timetable of construction workers by trade in order to satisfy the policy’s targeted hiring requirements.68 It is worth noting that the Construction Careers model was designed principally for large, government-subsidized projects. The model may well have to be adjusted to better fit smaller projects and smaller employers. In addition, the model emerged from settings featuring strong community-labor partnerships and high-quality training resources. The model may take longer to implement in a less politically or programmatically supportive environment. Indeed, there may be settings for which the model is not appropriate. 63 Id., Art. XIII, § 2. Mulligan-Hansel, supra note 56, at 54. 65 See White & Walsh, supra note 17. 66 CMTY. REDEVELOPMENT AGENCY OF THE CITY OF LOS ANGELES, CAL., RESOLUTION ADOPTING A POLICY REGARDING CONSTRUCTION CAREERS AND PROJECT STABILIZATION § III(I) [hereinafter CONSTRUCTION CAREERS POLICY]. 67 Id. at § IV. 68 Id. at § V(2). 64 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 19 A. Tenets The Green Construction Careers model, which expands on the model above by incorporating principles associated with environmental justice, follows four basic and interrelated tenets: (1) meaningful green development in low-income communities; (2) high quality jobs; (3) opportunity for low-income communities and communities of color to obtain sustained employment in the construction sector; and (4) high-quality job training. The essence of the model is to address each of these tenets, but a range of factors, including legal considerations, should contribute to the specific policy measures adopted in any particular jurisdiction. Accordingly, the discussion below sets forth a number of policy approaches available to advance each of the tenets. 1. Meaningful Green Development in Low-Income Communities One core function of the Green Construction Careers model is to make “green” development relevant and effective in lowincome communities. This starts with steering investment in green development to these communities. Fortunately, government policy has begun to lead the way with its own capital, thereby, one hopes, incentivizing the movement of private capital in this direction.69 This approach is reflected in the rapidly expanding low-income weatherization programs, which target low-income homes and neighborhoods for government-funded residential retrofits that enhance energy efficiency.70 Focusing investment in these areas helps directly address the health impacts of all types of pollution, which are 71 more concentrated in low-income communities. Further, it may 69 See U.S. Green Building Council, supra note 4. See Foshay & Schneider, supra note 47. 71 See, e.g., Sam Magavern, Affordable Housing and the Environment, In Buffalo, New York, (Legal Studies Research Paper No. 2008-07 July 9, 2007 at 21), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id= 70 BEACHFINAL.DOC 20 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY result in higher marginal energy-efficiency gains because older buildings, which tend to be the least efficient, are also more heavily concentrated in these communities.72 In order to maximize the impact of green development policy, the model also focuses investment within low-income communities on buildings that receive high levels of use by community members. These buildings, whether major centers of employment, recreation, or other public use, offer higher returns on environmental investment. For example, fixing a “sick” building can result in major improvements in the productivity and overall health of occupants.73 And, logically, a building that generates high levels of energy usage should be among the first to be made more energy-efficient. Finally, “greening the ghetto”74 isn’t just about making buildings more environmentally sound, especially under existing USGBC standards. The Green Construction Careers model calls for green building standards that substantially improve the environmental impact of buildings and that generate significant amounts of high-quality work in green construction, operations 1091549 (“Buffalo’s housing and environmental problems are not evenly distributed: they fall most heavily on people with low incomes and especially people of color. For example, the four zip codes with the highest rates of lead poisoning are on the predominantly African-American east side of the City of Buffalo, with incidence rates between three and five times higher than Erie County’s average.”); Douglas Houston et al., Structural Disparities of Urban Traffic in Southern California: Implications for Vehicle-Related Air Pollution Exposure in Minority and High-Poverty Neighborhoods, 26 J. URB. AFF. 565, 568 (2004) (“Minority and low-income areas in the Los Angeles region have borne a disproportionate level of stationary sources of air pollution including hazardous waste storage and disposal facilities (TSDFs) and Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) facilities.”). 72 Houston, supra note 71, at 578–80 (describing disproportionate concentration of older buildings in poor and minority communities). 73 Fisk, supra note 16, at 552–53. 74 Elizabeth Kolbert, Greening the Ghetto, NEW YORKER, Jan. 12, 2009, available at http://www.newyorker.com/reporting/2009/01/12/090112fa_fact_ kolbert (“The group’s goal is to broaden the appeal of the environmental movement and, at the same time, bring jobs to poor neighborhoods. Jones often says that he is trying to “green the ghetto.”). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 21 and maintenance. For example, while locating a building near major public transit lines is important, it does not have as much value within the Green Construction Careers framework as it does within the LEED standards, which do not place a priority on the type or number of jobs created by green projects.75 In contrast, installation of photovoltaic solar panels, where appropriate, because of its substantial impact on pollution and efficiency76 and its skilled work intensity, has high value in the model. 2. High Quality Jobs The model promotes high quality jobs in the construction sector for the benefit of workers, communities and investors alike. Of course, high quality jobs start with decent wages and benefits. In setting policy for the construction sector, government entities may rely on federal or state prevailing wage laws to help set a baseline. These laws establish wage standards based on the hourly wage, usual benefits and overtime paid in the largest city in each county to the majority of workers, laborers, and mechanics, and many units of government are already well equipped to enforce them.77 Community Workforce Agreements—project labor agreements containing provisions to ensure meaningful hiring of targeted workers—among unions and employers involved in green construction projects are also important to success. Under the Green Construction Careers model, the entity with overall responsibility for the project requires that all contractors and 75 MATTERA ET AL., supra note 20, at 21. See generally Soteris A. Kalogirou, Environmental Benefits of Domestic Solar Energy Systems, 45 ENERGY CONVERSION & MGMT. 3075 (2004). 77 Prevailing wages are set by the federal and state governments for each trade and occupation. The Davis-Bacon act requires the payment of prevailing wages on federally funded or assisted projects. 40 U.S.C.A. § 3142. Some states have similar statutes. See, e.g., CAL. LAB. CODE § 1770 et seq., 820 ILL. COMP. STAT. ANN. 130/0.01 et seq., N.Y. LABOR § 220, TEX. GOV’T CODE ANN. §§ 2258.021–.023. 76 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 22 subcontractors, before bidding on construction work on the project, become signatory to a Community Workforce Agreement that contains all of the equitable access measures described below. Such agreements establish uniform rules for hiring across entire projects and help to ensure labor peace. In the absence of such agreements, pre-existing hiring arrangements may—and often do—conflict with targeted hiring policies, creating obstacles to implementation. Moreover, successful targeted hiring initiatives such as the Port of Oakland, the Los Angeles Unified School District and the City of Los Angeles Construction Careers Policy have all relied on these kinds of agreements.78 In most cases, these agreements provide that union hiring halls serve as the primary source of all craft labor on a project,79 thereby providing an important assurance to unions that their membership will obtain work on the project. This assurance is vital to the basic political bargain at the heart of the model,80 and allows unions to open their ranks to new members. “Responsible contractor” measures offer a final, but equally important, means of ensuring job quality. These measures ensure that construction contractors with significant or repeated violations of workplace, tax and other laws are not utilized on construction projects on which the measures apply. The National Employment Law Project (NELP) has recently published a useful guide for policymakers seeking to adopt such measures.81 Based on a review of responsible contractor programs across the country, NELP recommends: (a) making responsibility review the first step in the bidder evaluation process, where 78 See supra notes 57, 66. Id. 80 See Mulligan-Hansel, supra note 56, at 20 (“Getting more low income workers and workers of color into union apprenticeship required increasing union contractors’ access to work”); Parkin, supra note 23, at 395 (“[T]he unions’ interest in opening up construction work to local residents served as a springboard for collaboration with a community that was skeptical as to whether unions with an exclusionary history should be trusted.”). 81 Paul K. Sonn & Tsedeye Gebreselassie, The Road to Responsible Contracting, NATI’L EMPLOYMENT LAW PROJECT, June 2009. 79 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 23 appropriate, through a “prequalification” system; (b) using a standardized responsibility questionnaire and quantified point system for contractors; and (c) publishing the names of firms seeking to bid or prequalify, in order to allow the public to report relevant information.82 3. Equitable Access to Construction Employment Opportunities The goal of careers in green construction for low-income individuals lies at the heart of the Green Construction Careers model. When designed and implemented properly, targeted hiring measures are an effective means of achieving this goal through policy.83 Federal, State and local policy have utilized different measures of this type.84 However, the successful policies, some of which are discussed above, have all set strict, high standards for construction work hours performed by targeted workers.85 Accordingly, the Green Construction Careers model reserves a specific percentage of construction work hours for low-income residents that reside in the same labor market as the project in question. There are myriad formulations of this standard, but the core components are: (a) a clear definition of the targeted beneficiary group based on income, barriers to employment and/or geography; (b) a percentage of construction work hours on the project reserved for workers from this group at the apprentice level, journey level or both; and (c) where a residency-based approach is adopted by state or local government, some means of accommodating the Privileges and 82 Id. at 10. Mulligan-Hansel, supra note 56, at 4. 84 See Parkin, supra note 23, at 383–384 (“Hiring preferences for local residents have become popular at all levels of government, with almost half the states and a number of local governments enacting some sort of local-hire legislation.”). 85 See supra notes 58–61, 63, 67 and accompanying text; MulliganHansel, supra note 56, at 51 (describing “clear requirements for local hiring” as among core components of local hire policies). 83 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 24 Immunities Clause issues discussed below.86 Another kind of policy measure aimed at facilitating the entry of disadvantaged individuals into the green construction involves targeted hiring from specially certified training programs. For example, a jurisdiction’s policy may set aside construction work hours for graduates of weatherization training programs certified by the jurisdiction based on standards for quality and enrollment of targeted individuals. This approach has emerged in the newly expanded residential weatherization sector, for which conventional apprenticeship training formats have not fully developed. In addition to New Jersey and Delaware, which are discussed below, the City of Portland recently adopted this approach for its Clean Energy Works home retrofit program.87 Because the local, low-income individuals targeted by the model are likely to be new to the construction trades, it is important to ensure that contractors on the subject project employ substantial numbers of apprentice-level workers. On projects in which contractors are utilizing state or federallyregistered apprenticeship programs, the standards governing those programs must contain ratios for the number of journey86 See, e.g., CONSTRUCTION CAREERS POLICY, supra note 66 (requiring that developers or prime contractors on major projects undertaken or subsidized by the agency reserve 30% of construction work hours for local residents, 10% of construction work hours for local, low-income or otherwise disadvantaged residents, and 50% of apprentice work hours for local residents). Id. § III(1). The policy also addresses the Privileges and Immunities Clause issue by excluding out-of-state workers from the targeted hiring calculation. Id. § III(3). 87 City of Portland, Bureau of Planning and Sustainability, Portland City Council Approves Community Workforce Agreement To Support Equity And Workforce Goals For Clean Energy Works Portland, Sept. 30, 2009, http:// www.portlandonline.com/bps/index.cfm?c=44851&a=265154; COMMUNITY WORKFORCE AGREEMENT ON STANDARDS AND COMMUNITY BENEFITS IN THE CLEAN ENERGY WORKS PORTLAND PILOT PROJECT, http://www.portland online.com/bps/index.cfm?c=50152&a=265161 § II(c) (“[C]ontractors and sub contractors will hire 100% of new worker/installer weatherization employees from a designated training program, as described in section IV, until 50% of contractor’s total non supervisory worker/installer weatherization employee monthly work hours on covered projects are performed by graduates of a designated training program.”). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 25 level workers to the number of apprentice-level workers in each craft.88 The Green Construction Careers model relies on a standard under which contractors must employ apprentice-level workers on the project in question to the maximum extent allowed by the applicable apprenticeship standards. Used in connection with Community Workforce Agreements, craft request forms offer an additional helpful tool in facilitating the referral of targeted workers between unions and contractors. These forms provide a standardized method for contractors to request that qualified targeted workers be admitted to the appropriate union and referred by that union for work on the project in question.89 Under the model, contractors are required to use, and unions are required to accept, such forms where they are properly completed and refer to a qualified targeted worker. Finally, the model relies upon a central coordinator to facilitate the interactions among the various parties and ensure that targeted workers progress smoothly through the system. Government entities may perform this function themselves, contract this function out, or require the entity with overall responsibility for the project to contract with a pre-qualified entity to perform this function. At a minimum, this central coordinator should: (a) establish a single point of contact for employers, unions, training providers, community organizations and targeted workers; (b) maintain an up-to-date list of qualified targeted workers; (c) facilitate outreach to targeted workers by qualified pre-apprenticeship training programs; (d) facilitate relationships among qualified apprenticeship and other training programs and employers to enable prompt referrals of targeted workers; and (e) where necessary, refer targeted workers to employers, qualified apprenticeship and other training programs and hiring halls. 88 29 C.F.R. § 29.5(b)(7). See, e.g., CONSTRUCTION CAREERS POLICY, supra note 66, at § IV(4)(d) (including among the terms for inclusion in a PLA, a requirement that Developer, Contractors, and Unions use and accept a standardized Craft Request Form and the procedures written therein to request any and all workers from Unions, including workers qualified as general dispatch and targeted workers). 89 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 26 Policymakers should also be aware that the mechanics of targeted hiring measures require close attention. Effective measures hold the key actors, such as developers and contractors, accountable to meaningful standards while affording flexibility to accommodate variations in performance across a project. For example, policymakers may wish to hold a developer or prime contractor ultimately responsible for numeric targets, including through monetary penalties, while holding individual contractors to more specific, straightforward “best efforts” requirements. 4. High Quality Training Construction work—done well—is physically and mentally demanding, and requires substantial knowledge and skill. In low-income communities, high quality training is a fundamental necessity. Successful Green Construction Careers programs must offer specialized training and preparation to ensure equitable access.90 This starts with high quality pre-apprenticeship programs. Such programs are characterized by (a) well-established partnerships with high-quality apprenticeship programs that ensure the pre-apprenticeship program will properly prepare targeted workers for apprenticeships and (b) strong track records of placing targeted workers into sustained careers in the construction trades.91 One example may be found in Newark, New Jersey, where the City, the Laborers’ International Union of North America and Garden State Alliance for a New 90 Kate Rubin & Doug Slater, Winning Construction Jobs for Local Residents, BRENNAN CENTER FOR JUSTICE AT NYU SCHOOL OF LAW, July 2005, at 31, available at http://www.brennancenter.org/content/resource/win ning_construction_jobs_for_local_residents_a_users_guide_for_community_o/ (“Experience with innovative workforce development programs around the country has shown that a comprehensive pre-apprenticeship program—one that includes recruitment, pre-apprenticeship training, case management, support services, job placement, and mentoring—is key for helping workers from diverse backgrounds succeed as construction trades apprentices.”). 91 Id. at 34. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 27 Economy, a community organization, sponsor a six-week preapprenticeship training program focused on improving environmental quality and reducing waste and leading to entry into the Laborers’ union.92 Note that this is the kind of training program that can provide a foundation for the alternative targeted hiring model discussed above in Sec. III(a)(iii). Of course, low-income individuals cannot be expected to drop everything and enroll in a pre-apprenticeship program that prevents them from holding down a regular job. Here, the model promotes the use of employment positions that compliment pre-apprenticeship training. For example, local governments may create or utilize existing pre-craft-helper or entry-level operations and maintenance positions for targeted workers. Ideally, employment in such positions will expose targeted workers to green construction and operations and maintenance practices followed by environmentally-sound government entities. Effective training programs will also accommodate participants’ particular needs, which may include childcare and other supportive services as well as record expungement. Because of the pivotal role of apprenticeship programs in the model, it is important that each construction contractor or subcontractor participate in an apprenticeship or other training program that meets fundamental standards for quality. For starters, apprenticeship programs that meet certain standards may register with the state or federal government.93 However, some registered programs—particularly those administered unilaterally by employers—have shown relatively poor results, 94 including for integration of minorities and women. Thus, 92 Ralph Ortega, Newark Dons a ‘Green Collar’ with Construction Training Program, NEW JERSEY STAR-LEDGER, Jan. 13, 2009, available at http://www.nj.com/news/ledger/jersey/index.ssf?/base/news-12/12318249661 24410.xml&coll=1. 93 Robert W. Glover & Cihan Bilginsoy, Registered Apprenticeship Training in the U.S. Construction Industry, 47 EDUC. & TRAINING 337, 339 (2005). 94 Id. at 342 (showing that jointly administered union apprenticeship programs have higher graduation and lower cancellation rates than non-union BEACHFINAL.DOC 28 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY policymakers should supplement this baseline. For example, policy can focus on the length of time over which a program has successfully operated and the number of individuals that a program has placed into sustained employment in the construction trades. Under the model, apprenticeship programs must also take steps to ensure that targeted workers progress through the system. These steps can include agreeing to admit particular numbers of targeted workers based on the needs of the project in question and/or to establish formalized relationships with preapprenticeship programs training targeted workers. Policymakers can ease the burden on apprenticeships participating in the Green Construction Careers program by either contributing to the cost of training targeted workers or requiring contractors to do so. B. Examples In the last year, coalitions of community, labor and environmental organizations have succeeded in advancing the Green Construction Careers model as a part of local, state and federal policy. The following examples, which cover a range of types of green development, each incorporate core components of the model. None have been in existence long enough to evaluate for effectiveness. Note that in some cases, the kind of development projects covered, including small scale residential weatherization, differ in important ways from the typically large-scale, multi-trade construction projects covered by the Construction Careers policies discussed above. 1. Los Angeles Green Retrofit and Workforce Ordinance On April 15, 2009, the City of Los Angeles enacted an ordinance establishing a “Green Retrofit and Workforce 95 Program.” Building on the City’s existing Construction Careers programs, including for women and minorities.) 95 CITY OF LOS ANGELES, CAL., ORDINANCE NO. 180633 (2009). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 29 policies96 and green building standards for large projects,97 the ordinance was the first in the nation to combine both green building and jobs standards. The ordinance was an important victory for the Los Angeles Apollo Alliance, which had campaigned for more than two years for its adoption.98 The ordinance requires the City to develop a comprehensive plan to retrofit all City-owned buildings over 7,500 square feet or constructed prior to 1978 with a goal of attaining at least a LEED-EB Silver rating99 and incorporating thirteen specific elements that ensure substantial environmental and health improvements as well as significant job creation.100 The ordinance prioritizes buildings located in low-income areas, buildings that pose health and safety risks, and buildings that provide direct services to residents.101 Under the guidance of a new Director in the Mayor’s office, an interagency taskforce and an advisory council of outside experts, including representatives of community, labor and environmental groups, the City will develop an innovative workforce system for the program.102 The system includes agreements with building trades unions to ensure job quality and labor peace on all retrofit work, targeted hiring measures 96 See supra note 19. CITY OF LOS ANGELES, CAL., ORDINANCE NO. 179820 (2008) (prohibiting issuance of building permit for projects at or above 50,000 gross square feet of floor area unless “[t]he project applicant . . . demonstrates that the Project meets the intent [emphasis added] of the criteria for certification at the LEED certified level”). 98 Strategic Concepts in Organizing and Policy Education, Green Jobs: The Los Angeles Apollo Alliance, http://www.scopela.org/article.php?list= type&type=35. 99 The LEED rating system offers different levels of certification, including “certified,” “silver,” “gold” and “platinum” based on the number of points earned in the LEED scoring system. See How to Achieve Certification, USGBC, available at http://www.usgbc.org/DisplayPage.aspx? CMSPageID=1991. 100 CITY OF LOS ANGELES, CAL., ORDINANCE NO. 180633, § 7.302(B) (2009). 101 Id. § 7.302(C). 102 Id. §§ 7.303, 7.304. 97 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 30 focused on low-income neighborhoods, and specialized green construction training programs.103 While the Los Angeles ordinance represents an important and path-breaking policy development, it certainly leaves room for policymakers to improve on the original. First and foremost, the ordinance neither requires the City to retrofit any building nor provides funding for the performance of retrofits. Further, the ordinance defers a number of important policy and program details for future discussion, including what targeted hiring measures, if any, will apply and what programs will be eligible to provide training. Standards for the retrofits are to be set forth in a “Plan,”104 which, as of this writing, has not yet been issued. 2. New Jersey State Weatherization Assistance Program Plan As noted, the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) recently passed by Congress and signed by President Barack Obama included a $5 billion dollar investment in the Weatherization Assistance Program (WAP), administered by the Department of Energy (DOE).105 The Weatherization Assistance Program is the largest residential energy conservation program in the nation and its funds are used to improve the energy efficiency of low-income dwellings. In New Jersey, nearly 4000 106 multi-family units will be weatherized under the program. In order to receive WAP funds, states are required to submit to the DOE a State “WAP Plan” setting forth in detail the 107 weatherization program and how it will be implemented. New 103 Id. Id. § 7.302(B). 105 AMERCIAN RECOVERY AND REINVESTMENT ACT OF 2009, at 24. 106 See OFFICE OF LOW-INCOME ENERGY CONSERVATION, N.J. DEP’T OF CMTY. AFFAIRS, 2009–2012 N.J. STATE PLAN AND GRANT APPLICATION FOR U.S. DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY’S AMERICAN RECOVERY AND REINVESTMENT ACT WEATHERIZATION ASSISTANCE PROGRAM GRANT, at 23, available at http://www.nj.gov/dca/divisions/dhcr/offices/docs/wapdraftarraplan.pdf. 107 10. C.F.R. § 440.14. (c) After the hearing, the State must prepare a final State plan that 104 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 31 Jersey’s WAP Plan for 2009-2012 incorporates a number of Green Construction Careers principles.108 First, the program is focused on low-income communities.109 To be eligible, a multiunit building must contain at least 66% low-income households.110 Second, the Plan integrates targeted hiring and high-quality training.111 Contractors must utilize a workforce that consists of at least 50% individuals that have graduated from certified weatherization training programs.112 Such programs are those that offer unrestricted enrollment and in which at least 50% of participants meet all of the following criteria: (1) Is a low-income individual; (2) Resides in a zip code containing at least one census tract with a rate of unemployment exceeding 150% of the unemployment rate for the state in which it is located; and (3) In the year prior to commencing work on the project in question, has not registered as an apprentice in a certified apprenticeship program or performed craft labor identifies and describes: (1) The production schedule for the State indicating projected expenditures and the number of dwelling units, including previously weatherized units which are expected to be weatherized annually during the program year; (2) The climatic conditions within the State; (3) The type of weatherization work to be done; (4) An estimate of the amount of energy to be conserved; (5) Each area to be served by a weatherization project within the State . . . (6) How the State plan is to be implemented. Id. § 440.14(c). 108 See OFFICE OF LOW-INCOME ENERGY CONSERVATION, N.J. DEP’T CMTY. AFFAIRS, supra note 106, at 38–39. 109 See id. at 23–24. 110 See id. at 24. 111 See id. at 39. 112 Id. OF BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 32 as a licensed journeyman.113 Finally, the Plan contains several strong measures to ensure job quality. All contractors performing weatherization work must pay employees the higher of (a) a state living wage estimated at $17.40 per hour or (b) the federal prevailing wage.114 Contractors must also provide “quality, affordable employer sponsored health insurance”115 and must attest that they meet an extensive and detailed set of responsible contractor requirements.116 All employees must complete at least 10 hours of OSHA safety training.117 Finally, all contractors are required to sign a labor peace agreement.118 The New Jersey plan incorporates most of the components of the Green Construction Careers Model. In addition to obtaining jobs for targeted workers, it also focuses on entry into specialized training programs, on which employers must in turn rely for workers. This approach seems appropriate where the primary objective is to move entry-level workers into entry-level construction positions. However, this approach also relies entirely on training programs that can effectively accomplish the plan’s goals, which may or may not exist in the jurisdiction in question. 3. Delaware State Weatherization Assistance Program Plan Delaware has also built the core principles of the Green Construction Careers model into its WAP Plan for years 2009 to 2012, which will govern $13,733,668 in federal funds and weatherization of a minimum of 1,526 homes.119 First, the 113 Id. Id. at 38. 115 Id. 116 Id. at 39. 117 Id. 118 Id. 119 DEL. HEALTH AND SOCIAL SERV., AMERICAN RECOVERY AND REINVESTMENT ACT WEATHERIZATION PROGRAM STATE PLAN PROGRAM 114 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 33 program targets investment to low-income residences.120 Buildings qualifying for weatherization assistance are dwelling units occupied by a family whose income is at or below 200 percent of poverty as determined in accordance with criteria established by the Director of the U.S. Office of Management and Budget and adopted by the State of Delaware.121 Second, the Plan also integrates targeted hiring measures.122 Under the Plan, all employers receiving Recovery Act funds to provide residential energy efficiency services are required to utilize currently enrolled trainees or graduates of programs that serve low-income communities to perform at least 33% of work hours.123 Third, the Plan helps ensure job quality by requiring that employer-paid family health coverage is provided “to all energy auditors, supervisors and installers whose wages are paid in whole or in part with Recovery Act funds.”124 The plan also requires employees supervising or performing energy audit or installation work to complete a state-recognized training program.125 Finally, high quality training is also a key piece of the plan. The Delaware Weatherization Assistance Program (WAP) has formed a partnership with the Laborers International Union of North America Local 55 to provide specialized workforce training.126 This training, in the form of 5-week intensive training modules, will be performed at a new training facility purchased by the union for this purpose.127 In addition, the WAP is participating in a statewide consortium that includes educational institutions, contractors, labor unions, the state’s YEAR 2009–2012, at 4, available at http://recovery.delaware.gov/documents/ grant-applications/Weatherization-Assistance-Program.pdf [hereinafter DELAWARE WEATHERIZATION PROGRAM]. 120 Id. at 15. 121 Id. 122 Id. at 22. 123 Id. 124 Id. at 58 125 Id. 126 Id. at 20. 127 Id. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 34 utility industry, and state and local government to “build a ‘career ladder’ for the weatherization sector.”128 The consortium is chaired by a senior official of Delaware Technical and Community College and is preparing a coordinated program of certificate training, associate and 4-year degree opportunities.129 This program, while similar to New Jersey’s, also strays a bit further from the model in terms of its approach to targeted hiring. As noted, the targeted hiring requirement relates to enrolled trainees or graduates of programs that merely serve low-income communities.130 Any number of training programs might reasonably meet that criteria. Fortunately, it appears that the specialized LIUNA training program will play a prominent role in Delaware’s Plan implementation, ideally crowding out any low-road training operators.131 4. The American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 (H.R. 2454) In June 2009, the U.S. House of Representatives passed H.R. 2454, the American Clean Energy and Security Act, which included a Green Construction Careers Demonstration Project (“GCCDP”). The purpose of the GCCDP is to “promote middle class careers and quality employment practices in the green construction sector among targeted workers.”132 The Act establishes programs and legal standards relating to a vast universe of green construction projects, including, to name just a few: construction of facilities related to carbon capture and 133 sequestration; construction of facilities that manufacture plugin vehicles or their batteries;134 manufacturing of energy efficient 128 Id. at 7. Id. 130 See Cummings & Boutcher, supra note 11 and accompanying text. 131 See DELAWARE WEATHERIZATION PROGRAM, supra note 119, at 1. 132 American Clean Energy and Security Act, H.R. 2454, 111th Cong. § 424A(a) (2009). 133 See id. at §§ 114, 115. 134 Id. § 116. 129 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 35 homes;135 and energy efficiency building retrofits.136 Any project, “including residential retrofitting projects, funded directly by or assisted in whole or in part by or through the Federal Government pursuant to [the] Act or by any other entity established in accordance with [the] Act” is eligible for inclusion in the GCCDP.137 The Act, while incorporating core components of the Green Construction Careers model, gives substantial discretion to the Secretary of Labor to structure and administer the GCCDP. For starters, the Secretary, in consultation with the Secretaries of Energy, must establish which projects will be a part of the GCCDP.138 There is no limitation on the number, size or cost of projects that may be covered, and the Secretaries may expand the project in the future.139 The Secretaries are specifically empowered to set a percentage of targeted workers to be hired on covered projects.140 The Act devotes several provisions to ensuring both job quality and high quality training. The Secretaries are explicitly permitted to require Project Labor Agreements on GCCDP projects.141 On covered projects, contractors and subcontractors must have a written agreement with quality apprenticeship or training programs, which are those defined in § 3(1) of the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974.142 The 135 See id. § 203. See id. § 202. 137 Id. § 424A(a). 138 Id. § 424A(a). 139 See id. § 424A(c). 140 See id. § 424A(b). The Act defines targeted workers to include groups targeted under the Work Opportunity Tax Credit (including youth, veterans and public benefits recipients), those in low-income families and households, and displaced homemakers. Id. § 424A(e). 141 Id. § 424A(h). 142 Id. § 424A(g). The statute for the Act, 29 U.S.C. 1002(1), defines an “employee benefit welfare plan” as “any plan, fund, or program which was heretofore or is hereafter established or maintained by an employer or by an employee organization, or by both, to the extent that such plan, fund, or program was established or is maintained for the purpose of providing for its participants or their beneficiaries, through the purchase of insurance or 136 BEACHFINAL.DOC 36 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY apprenticeship and training programs must, in turn, have written agreements with pre-apprenticeship programs that have a demonstrated ability to recruit and prepare targeted workers for apprenticeship program admission.143 As with the Los Angeles ordinance, the GCCDP reflects the core principles of the Green Construction Careers model, but leaves many vital matters to the discretion of the implementing agency. For example, the Department could elect not to include any construction projects in the GCCDP, or to not require meaningful targeted hiring measures or community workforce agreements. In addition, the Department may encounter a political and/or bureaucratic thicket in trying to implement the program, which focuses on projects funded by other agencies through a variety of administrative channels. IV. LEGAL CONSIDERATIONS FOR STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS ADOPTING GREEN CONSTRUCTION CAREERS POLICIES The core provisions of the Green Construction Careers model, if adopted as state or local regulation, give rise to a number of noteworthy legal considerations. Counsel for policymakers wishing to adopt some version of the model should be well apprised of these issues, while appreciating that none have yet created an obstacle to adoption or implementation in the cases discussed above. The legal issues implicated by the model and discussed in this section include: pre-emption of labor-related standards by the National Labor Relations Act; and otherwise . . . apprenticeship or other training programs . . . .” 29 U.S.C. § 1002(1). This standard allows both union and non-union programs to participate. The California Supreme Court has held that an apprenticeship program created by a nonunion group of contractors (including a trust established to receive and manage employer contributions to fund program, and written standards under which program operates) was an “employee welfare benefit plan” under ERISA. S. Cal. Chapter of Associated Builders v. Calif. Apprenticeship Council, 841 P.2d 1011, 1019–20 (1992). 143 American Clean Energy and Security Act, H.R. 2454, 111th Cong. § 424A(g)(1). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 37 conflict of residency-based targeted hiring measures with the Privileges and Immunities Clause of Article VI of the U.S. Constitution, the Commerce Clause of Article I of the U.S. Constitution, the Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment to the U.S. Constitution, and the Federal Highway Administration’s regulatory prohibition against local hiring preferences. This section discusses each of these legal issues and explores ways that policymakers seeking to adopt Green Construction Careers measures in states and municipalities can avert obstacles the issues may raise. Note that a jurisdiction may follow the tenets of the construction careers model using policy measures that do not implicate the legal issues discussed below. For example, a jurisdiction could address job quality using measures such as living wage requirements or modest responsible contractor standards that do not give rise to significant National Labor Relations Act pre-emption concerns. Or a jurisdiction could have a targeted hiring program without the geographically-based residency requirements that implicate a number of legal issues. But policymakers rightly want measures that implicate the legal issues discussed below because of effectiveness of measures like Community Workforce Agreements and political and policy desirability of certain types of geography-based targeting. Fortunately, in general, proper findings and careful drafting will enable avoidance of the issues discussed below, especially where the jurisdiction has adopted Green Construction Careers measures in connection with its role as a market participant. A. Pre-emption of Labor-Related Provisions by National Labor Relations Act 144 which The National Labor Relations Act (“NLRA”), governs labor organizing and the relationship between unions 145 and employers, contains no express pre-emption provision. 144 145 (2008). 29 U.S.C. § 151–69. Chamber of Commerce of the U.S. v. Brown, 128 S. Ct. 2408, 2412 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 38 However, the U.S. Supreme Court has articulated two implied pre-emption doctrines.146 The first, known as Garmon preemption,147 “is intended to preclude state interference with the National Labor Relations Board’s interpretation and active enforcement of the ‘integrated scheme of regulation’ established by the NLRA.”148The Garmon pre-emption doctrine forbids state regulation of activities that the NLRA (a) protects, (b) makes an unfair labor practice, or (c) arguably protects or prohibits.149The second, known as Machinists pre-emption, prohibits state regulation of conduct that Congress intended be unregulated and left to be controlled by the “free play of economic forces.”150The Machinists doctrine focuses on state regulation of economic weapons available to employers and workers.151 However, as discussed below, two important exceptions limit the scope of the Garmon and Machinists doctrines. The NLRA will only pre-empt regulatory actions of states and subdivisions thereof. The U.S. Supreme Court and several circuit courts have recognized that a state or municipality acting as a participant in the market that is the subject of the government-adopted standard at issue will not be subject to NLRA pre-emption.152 It is worth noting that the Green 146 147 Id. See San Diego Bldg. Trades Council v. Garmon, 359 U.S. 236 (1959). 148 Golden State Transit Corp. v. City of Los Angeles, 475 U.S. 608 (1986). 149 Wis. Dep’t of Indus., Labor & Human Relations. v. Gould, Inc., 475 U.S. 282 (1986). 150 Machinists v. Wis. Employment Relations Comm’n, 427 U.S. 132 (1976) (quoting NLRB v. Nash-Finch Co., 404 U.S. 138 (1971)). 151 See Golden State Transit Corp. v. City of Los Angeles, 475 U.S. 608 (1986) (overturning a city’s decision not to renew company’s cab license unless the company resolved a labor dispute with its employees); Machinists, 427 U.S. at 155 (invalidating state order enjoining union and its members from continuing to refuse to work overtime); Chamber of Commerce of the U.S. v. Bragdon, 64 F.3d 497, 504 (9th Cir. 1995) (invalidating a wage increase regulation that applied to employees working on private projects costing over $500,000). 152 Bldg. & Construction Trades Council v. Associated Builders & BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 39 Construction Careers model seems most likely to be applied in contexts in which the policymaking entity is acting as a market participant. The Los Angeles Green Retrofit ordinance and the New Jersey and Delaware weatherization program plans discussed above each provide an example of standards governing market participation. In Los Angeles, the ordinance establishes rules related to the City’s own retrofitting ((i.e., retrofitting undertaken by city employees or contractors) of City buildings.153 The New Jersey and Delaware program plans describe state rules governing the expenditure of state and federal funds for weatherization.154 In each case, the government entity is acting as a participant in the building retrofit market to which its standards apply and should thus qualify as a market participant for purposes of NLRA pre-emption analysis. State and local governments seeking to adopt the Green Construction Careers model in connection with the provision of subsidies,155 or the leasing of land or space should take note of varied case law on the question of whether these actions provide a basis for qualifying as a market participant.156 Further, the Contractors of the Metro. Dist., 507 U.S. 218, 227, 229 (1993) (“[NLRA] pre-emption doctrines apply only to state regulation [and] a State may act without offending the pre-emption principles of the NLRA when it acts as a proprietor.”). 153 See supra Part III(b)(i). 154 See supra Part III(b)(ii) and (iii). 155 In Associated Builders & Contractors v. City of Providence, the court examined a local regulation that required the execution of a PLA for private projects in exchange for favorable tax treatment. 108 F. Supp. 2d 73 (D.R.I. 2000). The court reasoned that because favorable tax treatment did not constitute direct market participation akin to purchasing/selling goods/services, the local tax regulation was pre-empted by the NLRA. Id. However, in Hotel Employees & Rest. Employees Union, Local 57 v. Sage Hospitality Res., the court held that the City was not preempted from requiring parties receiving tax increment financing to sign a labor neutrality agreement. 390 F.3d 206, 207–208 (3rd Cir. 2004). 156 See, e.g., Four T’s, Inc. v. Little Rock Mun. Airport Comm’n, 108 F.3d 909 (8th Cir. 1997) (holding that airport participating in rental car market by renting counter space and parking spaces to rental car companies); Transport Limousine of Long Island, Inc. v. Port Auth. of N.Y. and N.J., 571 F. Supp 576 (E.D.N.Y. 1983) (holding that Port Authority’s imposition BEACHFINAL.DOC 40 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY U.S. Supreme Court has indicated that the mere granting of a franchise is not adequate to qualify a government entity as a participant in the market for which the franchise is granted.157 This issue is more apt to occur in the service contract context, but could be important where, for example, a private party is engaged in building operations and maintenance under a franchise agreement. At bottom, while this area of law is complex, and, on some questions, unclear, the basic rule established in the Boston Harbor case158—that government entities applying standards to their sponsored projects may avoid NLRA pre-emption—should give policymakers solid footing from which to shape green development. Policymakers should also be aware that the basis of the policy in dispute is an important component of pre-emption analysis.159 For example, in Associated Builders & Contractors, of fees on limousine services in exchange for counter space qualified Port Authority as participant in market for ground transportation services). Compare J.L. Smith v. Dept. of Agric. of the State of Ga., 630 F.2d 1081, 1083 (5th Cir. 1981) (holding that market participant doctrine did not apply to state regulation of space assignment at state-owned farmer’s market); Aeroground v. City and County of San Francisco, 170 F. Supp. 2d. 950 (N.D. Cal. 2001) (holding that airport not acting as market participant in promulgating rule requiring certain employers on the airport site to enter into card check agreements with registered unions). 157 See Golden State, 475 U.S. at 615, 618 (the Court explicitly rejected the argument that a state regulation was immune from Machinists pre-emption because the regulation took the form of a traditional use of local authority to grant a benefit, and pre-empted an exercise of a city’s decision to grant a taxi franchise). 158 See Bldg. & Construction Trades Council v. Associated Builders & Contractors of the Metro. Dist., 507 U.S. 218, 227, 229 (1993). 159 In Building & Construction Trades Council, the U.S. Supreme Court examined a state bid specification for a state owned and managed project that required contractors and subcontractors to agree to a Project Labor Agreement (PLA) containing particular terms. 507 U.S. 218, 221–22 (1993). The court found that the state was acting as a purchaser of services; that the state was “attempting to ensure an efficient project that would be completed as quickly and effectively as possible at the lowest cost;” that the bid specification was specifically tailored to one particular job; and that project BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 41 Inc. v. City of Seward, the Ninth Circuit determined that the state acted as a market participant when it required the winning bidder on a public works project to comply with a work preservation clause contained in the City’s contract.160 The court noted that the City “was not driven by regulatory concerns, but by legitimate management concerns that may lead any employer, public or private, to agree to a work preservation clause.”161 The Machinists and Garmon doctrines are also limited by the principle that minimum standards that merely create a background for collective bargaining are not pre-empted by the NLRA. In Fort Halifax Packing Co. v. Coyne162 and Metropolitan Life Insurance v. Massachusetts,163 the Supreme Court held that laws setting minimum health benefits and minimum severance payments were not pre-empted.164Many of the core components of the Green Construction Careers model may also be characterized as falling into this category of regulation. The following discusses more specifically the risk of NLRA pre-emption associated with some of the core components of the Green Construction Careers model. labor agreements were specifically contemplated under the NLRA. Id. at 232. The Court concluded that there was therefore “no basis on which to distinguish the incentives at work here from those that operate elsewhere in the construction industry” and held that the state acted as a market participant, not as a regulator. Id. 160 966 F.2d 492, 496–98 (9th Cir. 1992). 161 Id. at 496 (emphasis added). 162 482 U.S. 1, 22 (1987) (holding that the NLRA did not pre-empt a state law requiring minimum severance payments when a factory closes). 163 471 U.S. 724, 758 (1985) (holding NLRA did not pre-empt state law that set minimum health care benefits). 164 Id.; see also Dillingham Constr. N.A. v. County of Sonoma, 190 F.3d 1034, 1038–39 (9th Cir. 1999) (holding NLRA did not pre-empt California law that required public works employers to pay prevailing wages to apprentices); Contract Servs. Network v. Aubry, 62 F.3d 294, 298–99 (9th Cir. 1995) (holding NLRA did not pre-empt California law that required employers to contribute to unemployment and workers’ compensation funds). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 42 1. Targeted Hiring In order to withstand a legal challenge under the NLRA preemption doctrines, it is important that the targeted hiring measures not have a direct effect on the collective bargaining process. In Hudson County Building and Construction Trades Council, AFL-CIO v. City of Jersey City, the court reviewed a motion for summary judgment by plaintiff Trades Council, which had challenged a city targeted hiring ordinance. The ordinance required subsidized developers to employ 51% Jersey City residents (51% of whom had to be minority and 7% of whom had to be women) and to require subcontractors to enter local hiring agreements containing good faith obligations.165 The ordinance further required unions with whom subcontractors had referral agreements to submit signed statements that the unions would act consistently with the good faith obligations.166 If an employer could not meet its good faith obligations because of the non-compliance of a union, the employer was required to notify the City of its referral needs to meet the goal and consider those referred by the City without regard to any agreement it had with a union.167 The court considered plaintiff’s argument that the Garmon doctrine applied because the ordinance required a unilateral change in the hiring hall procedure designated in the collective bargaining agreement, and that such a unilateral change was an unfair labor practice prohibited by the NLRA.168 The court held that there were issues of material fact that prevented it from granting summary judgment, noting in particular that Garmon pre-emption depends on the factual determination of whether and how the city ordinance regulates the collective bargaining process, rather than on the substantive terms of the bargain that 169 is struck. 165 166 167 168 169 960 F. Supp. 823, 826–27 (D.N.J. 1996). Id. at 827. Id. Id. at 833. Id. at 834. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 43 The court also considered the argument that the ordinance was subject to Machinists pre-emption because hiring hall provisions, a mandatory subject of negotiations, had been left to the “free play of economic forces.”170 The court denied summary judgment, noting that a factual question remained as to whether the ordinance affected the conduct of unions and employers in the collective bargaining process.171 Thus, even though the court found that Congress left these types of provisions to the free play of economic forces, the court would not automatically find Machinist pre-emption in the absence of evidence of an actual effect on collective bargaining. Policymakers and their counsel should also consider the perspective in addressing this issue that, following the holdings in Metropolitan Life and Fort Halifax, modest targeted hiring requirements like those at issue in Jersey City will almost never directly impact the collective bargaining process in a way that triggers NLRA pre-emption. As to Garmon pre-emption, Metropolitan Life may be read to say that, while an issue may be the subject of collective bargaining, where the NLRA is silent as to that issue, as it is regarding hiring hall referral procedures, the jurisdiction cannot be said to have sought to interfere with the National Labor Relations Board’s interpretation and enforcement of the NLRA.172 As to Machinists pre-emption, Metropolitan Life and Fort Halifax also mean that the NLRA is not concerned with regulations that, like targeted hiring 170 Id. Id. 172 In Metropolitan Life, plaintiffs challenged a Massachusetts statute requiring that certain health insurance policies purchased by employers provide minimum mental health benefits. Because some of these plans were purchased pursuant to collective bargaining agreements, the terms of the plans were subject to collective bargaining, and plaintiffs argued that the statute “mandate[d] the terms of collective-bargaining agreements.” 471 U.S. 724, 749 (1985). The Court rejected the Garmon argument, stating, “there is no claim here that Massachusetts has sought to regulate or prohibit any conduct subject to the regulatory jurisdiction of the NLRB, since the [NLRA] is silent as to the substantive provisions of welfare-benefit plans.” Id. at 748– 49. 171 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 44 measures, may affect the substantive terms of a collective bargaining agreement, but do not affect the relative positions of the parties to that agreement.173 2. Project Labor Agreements Community Workforce Agreements—project labor agreements containing targeted hiring provisions—are central to the Green Construction Careers model. However, requiring the use of such agreements outside the market participant context may create substantial risk of pre-emption by the NLRA. In Associated Builders & Contractors v. Providence, the federal district court applied the Machinists pre-emption doctrine to hold that the NLRA pre-empted a local regulation requiring the execution of a project labor agreement for private project receiving favorable tax treatment from the City.174 The court reasoned that by influencing the decisions of private employers and employees as to whether or not, and with whom, to bargain, the city clearly implicated conduct Congress meant to leave unregulated.175 3. Apprenticeship Program Participation Requiring contractors to participate in high-quality apprenticeship programs is crucial to ensuring that targeted workers obtain sustained careers in green construction. On its face, a requirement that contractors obtain apprentices from, and provide support to, apprenticeship programs meeting high standards for quality would not appear to be pre-empted by the NLRA. The Ninth Circuit has held that a state prevailing wage 173 In Metropolitan Life, the Court opined, “[t]he NLRA is concerned primarily with establishing an equitable process for determining terms and conditions of employment, and not with particular substantive terms of the bargain that is struck when the parties are negotiating from relatively equal positions.” Id. at 753; see also Fort Halifax Packing Co. v. Coyne, 482 U.S. 1, 20 (1987). 174 108 F. Supp. 2d 73, 84 (D.R.I. 2000). 175 Id. at 81. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 45 law for apprentices was not pre-empted under the Machinists doctrine in part because “federal law contemplates and permits regulation of apprenticeship standards.”176 4. Responsible Contractor Many states and localities have used responsible contractor requirements in connection with their procurement and other market participation activities.177 However, policymakers designing such requirements should be aware of Wisconsin Dept. of Industry v. Gould Inc., in which the U.S. Supreme Court held that the NLRA pre-empted a Wisconsin statute that forbade state procurement agents from using state funds to purchase products made or sold by NLRA violators.178 The court reasoned that because the statute functioned as a supplemental sanction for violations of the NLRA, it conflicted with the National Labor Relations Board’s comprehensive regulation of industrial relations in precisely the same way as would a prohibition against private parties within the State doing business with repeat labor law violators.179 Thus, policymakers should avoid creating such supplemental sanctions for NLRA violations in designing responsible contractor requirements. 5. Minimum Wage, Benefit and Workplace Standards As noted, the NRLA does not pre-empt generally applicable minimum wage, benefit or other minimum labor standards that affect union and non-union employees equally, and neither encourage nor discourage the collective-bargaining processes 180 that are the subject of the NLRA. States and localities wishing 176 Dillingham Constr. N.A. v. County of Sonoma, 190 F.3d 1034, 1039 (9th Cir. 1999). 177 Sonn & Gebreselassie, supra note 81, at 8. 178 475 U.S. 282 (1986). 179 Id. at 286–87. 180 See Metro. Life Ins. Co. v. Massachusetts, 471 U.S. 724, 755 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 46 to include such minimum standards in green construction careers measures may look to Associated Builders & Contractors of Southern California v. Nunn, in which the Ninth Circuit held that California regulations establishing minimum wages and benefits on public and private construction projects for stateregistered apprentices survived Machinists pre-emption because the law only established minimum labor standards and because federal law permits state regulation of apprenticeship standards.181However, policymakers must also take note of Chamber of Commerce of the United States v. Bragdon, in which the Ninth Circuit determined that a Contra Costa county ordinance requiring payment of prevailing wages on certain types of private industrial construction projects costing over $ 500,000 was pre-empted by the NLRA.182 B. Conflict of Targeted Hiring Measures with the Privileges and Immunities Clause of Article IV of the U.S. Constitution The Privileges and Immunities Clause of Article IV of the United States Constitution provides that “the Citizens of each State shall be entitled to all Privileges and Immunities of Citizens in the several States.”183 The targeted hiring measures described in the Green Construction Careers model, to the extent they result in a preference scheme adverse to out-of-state workers, might be said to interfere with those workers’ ability to pursue private employment, which the U.S. Supreme Court has held is a fundamental right for purposes of the Privileges and 184 Immunities Clause. The Court has rejected the argument that discrimination based on municipal—as opposed to state— (1985). 181 356 F.3d 979, 990–91 (9th Cir. 2004). 64 F.3d 497 (9th Cir. 1995); see also 520 South Michigan Avenue Associates, LTD. v. Congress Plaza Hotel & Convention Center, 549 F. 3d 1119 (2008). 183 U.S. CONST. art. IV, § 2, cl. 1. 184 See United Bldg. & Construction Trades Council of Camden v. Mayor of Camden, 465 U.S. 208, 219 (1984). 182 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 47 residency does not implicate the Clause.185 However, the Privileges and Immunities Clause only precludes discrimination against non-residents when the governmental action burdens one of the privileges and immunities protected under the clause, and the government does not have a “substantial reason” for the difference in treatment or the discrimination practiced against the nonresidents does not bear a “substantial relationship” to the government’s objectives.186 In accordance with this deferential standard, local governments have adopted targeted hiring measures based on an explicitly stated desire to address poverty and unemployment.187 Wisely, these entities have made extensive findings about the poverty and unemployment they hope to address and the way in which targeted hiring measures accomplish that goal.188 185 Id. at 215–16. Supreme Court of N.H. v. Piper, 470 U.S. 274, 284 (1985). 187 See, e.g., CONSTRUCTION CAREERS POLICY, supra note 66, at 1 (“[R]edevelopment objectives will be advanced by targeting construction employment and training opportunities in ways calculated (i) to mitigate the harms caused by geographically-concentrated poverty, (ii) to fight unemployment and underemployment in vulnerable populations and neighborhoods, including under-represented populations, populations with employment barriers and youth, (iii) to advance the skills of the local labor pool, including youth, to enable workers to earn wages that will assist them in moving out of poverty, (iv) to provide links to career paths for vulnerable populations and Local Residents . . . .”). 188 For example, in Jersey City, the City defended its ordinance by pointing to poverty and unemployment rates there that were higher than those of surrounding municipalities. Hudson County Bldg. & Constr. Trades Council v. Jersey City, 960 F. Supp. 823, 830–31 (D.N.J. 1996). The court, in declining summary judgment against the City, noted that the City still needed to show that “out-of-state workers are a source of unemployment and poverty within its borders.” Id. at 831. In W.C.M. Window Co. v. Bernardi, the Seventh Circuit invalidated an Illinois statute that provided that the contractor on “any public works project or improvement for the State of Illinois or any political subdivision, municipal corporation or other governmental unit thereof shall employ only Illinois laborers on such project or improvement,” unless the contractor certifies, and the contracting officer finds, that Illinois laborers either “are not available, or are incapable of performing the particular type of work involved . . . .” 730 F.2d 486, 489 186 BEACHFINAL.DOC 48 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY In United Building & Construction Trades Council of Camden County v. Mayor & City of Camden, the U.S. Supreme Court examined a Privileges and Immunities challenge189 to an ordinance of the City of Camden, New Jersey that required at least 40% of the employees of contractors and subcontractors working on city-funded construction projects to be Camden residents.190 During the course of litigation, the ordinance was amended to apply to any construction project “funded in whole or in part with City funds or funds which the City expends or administers in accordance with the terms of a grant.”191 Additionally, “the 40% resident-hiring requirement was changed from a strict ‘quota’ to a ‘goal’ with which developers and (7th Cir. 1984) (omission in original) (quoting the Illinois statute). The statute defined “Illinois laborers” as a worker who had been a resident of Illinois for at least a year. Id. at 494. The court found that the state had not put forth any evidence regarding benefits of a residents-preference law in dealing with a problem created by nonresidents. Id. at 497. In Util. Contrs. Ass’n of New Eng. v. City of Worcester, the court invalidated an ordinance reserving 50% of work hours on city public works projects for city residents, despite evidence of high unemployment, because the city had not shown that the unemployment was caused by out-of-state residents. 236 F. Supp. 2d 113, 115 (2002). 189 Initially, the appellant trade union raised Commerce Clause and Equal Protection arguments as well. United Bldg. & Construction Trades Council of Camden County, 465 U.S. at 212. Appellant abandoned its Commerce Clause argument in light of the Supreme Court’s decision in White v. Mass. Council of Constr. Employers, which held a mayor’s executive order immune from scrutiny under a “market participation” exception to the Commerce Clause. 460 U.S. 204, 213 (1983) (relying upon the decision in 460 U.S. 204 (1983). Appellants abandoned their Equal Protection argument when the ordinance was amended to eliminate a one-year residency requirement. Id. 190 465 U.S. at 210. The ordinance specifically applied, “[w]herever the City of Camden spends funds derived from any public source for construction contracts or where the City of Camden confers a direct financial benefit upon a party, but excluding the grant of a property tax abatement, the fair market value of which exceeds $ 50,000.00, the provisions of this ordinance shall apply . . . . The provisions of this ordinance shall also apply to the development and construction of all residential housing of four (4) units or less.” Id. at 211 n.3 (omission in original) (quoting the ordinance at issue). 191 Id. at 214 (quoting the appellees’ brief). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 49 contractors were to make ‘every good faith effort’” to comply.192 Having concluded that the ordinance burdened a fundamental right, the Court analyzed the ordinance’s relationship to the government’s objectives.193 The City argued that “the ordinance [was] necessary to counteract grave economic and social ills [such as] unemployment, a sharp decline in population, and a reduction in the number of businesses located in the city, [each of which resulted in] eroded property values and a depleted . . . tax base.”194 The resident-hiring preference was designed, the city contended, to increase the number of employed persons living in Camden and to arrest the “middleclass flight” plaguing the city.195 The city also argued that all non-Camden residents employed on city public works projects, whether they reside in New Jersey or Pennsylvania, constitute a “source of the evil at which the statute is aimed.”196 The Court reversed the New Jersey Supreme Court’s decision to uphold the ordinance on the ground that the record contained insufficient facts to evaluate the City’s justification because there had never 197 been a trial or findings of fact. The case ultimately settled on remand, without a determination of whether the ordinance would have violated the Privileges and Immunities clause. The U.S. Supreme Court does accord deference to states and localities in analyzing “local evils” and prescribing “appropriate cures.”198 In particular, the Court has given deference to state and local governments that are “merely setting conditions on the expenditure of funds” that they control.199 One district court has followed that doctrine to hold that a city-contract term requiring airport security contractors to hire Detroit residents did not run afoul of the Privileges and Immunities Clause because the city 192 Id. (quoting the appellees’ brief). Id. at 222. 194 Id. 195 Id. 196 Id. at 223. 197 Id. 198 Toomer v. Witsell, 334 U.S. 385, 396 (1948). 199 United Bldg. & Construction Trades Council of Camden County, 465 U.S. at 223. 193 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 50 used only its own monies to purchase the services.200 However, the Camden case, which involved projects “funded in whole or in part by the city”, suggests there are limits to this deference.201 Importantly, the Privileges and Immunities Clause does not apply to direct public employment because there is no privilege or fundamental right to direct employment with a governmental institution.202 States and localities seeking to adopt targeted hiring measures that may discriminate against out-of-state workers may thus wish to use such measures to remedy unemployment or poverty in areas where those “local evils” can be shown to be (a) higher than in other areas and (b) caused by out-of-state workers occupying employment positions in the targeted sector. However, states and localities may have more leeway than Camden seems to suggest. The Seventh Circuit has noted several kinds of evidence that a jurisdiction might use to justify discrimination against out-of-state workers in the construction sector, each relating principally to the benefit to the jurisdiction.203 This evidence included: the unemployment rate in [the jurisdiction’s] construction industry; what such unemployment cost the jurisdiction; whether it would be significantly increased by throwing open public construction projects to nonresidents; and whether the costs—if any—to the jurisdiction of allowing nonresident labor on such projects, costs in higher unemployment or welfare benefits paid unemployed construction workers or their families, were likely to exceed any cost savings in public construction from hiring nonresident 204 workers. An approach that likely creates a complete defense to a 200 Jones v. J.J. Sec., Inc. 767 F.Supp. 151 (E.D. Mich. 1991). United Bldg. & Construction Trades Council of Camden County, 465 U.S. at 221. 202 Mass. Bd. of Retirement v. Murgia, 427 U.S. 307, 313 (1976); Salem Blue Collar Workers Ass’n v. City of Salem 33 F.3d 265, 270 (3rd Cir. 1994). 203 W.C.M. Window Co. v. Bernardi, 730 F.2d 486, 498 (7th Cir. 1984). 204 Id. 201 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 51 Privileges and Immunities challenge is to simply exempt out-ofstate workers from targeted hiring calculations, as the City of Cleveland has done in its “Resident Employment Law.”205 That law requires that contracts related to construction projects under which the city provides more than $100,000 in assistance contain a provision ensuring that city residents will perform at least twenty percent of all “Construction Worker Hours.”206 The law simply excludes hours worked by non-Ohio residents from the definition of “Construction Worker Hours.”207 The Sixth Circuit has held that the Cleveland Resident Employment Law does not violate Title 23 C.F.R. § 635.117(b), which bars contract requirements that discriminate against labor from other 208 states or territories. Notably, the court looked to Privileges and Immunities jurisprudence to establish the vital distinction between interstate and intrastate discrimination based on residency.209 Given these options, policymakers should consider tracking hours worked by out-of-state residents in the sector that will be the subject of residency-based targeted hiring measures. Where the emerging data shows that few out-of-state workers are employed in the sector, policymakers may opt for the Cleveland approach, thereby creating a legal defense to a Privileges and Immunities challenge while causing minimal disruption to targeted hiring goals. Alternatively, where the emerging data shows a substantial number of out-of-state workers in the sector, a locality may use that data as a basis for finding a particular 205 CLEVELAND, OH. ADMIN. CODE tit. XV, ch. 188 (2009). Id. § 188.02. 207 Id. § 188.01(c). 208 City of Cleveland v. Ohio Dept. of Transport., 508 F.3d 827, 847 (6th Cir. 2007) (“Cleveland’s ordinance was drafted to avoid reaching contractors who hire only out-of-state workers, so it does not ‘discriminate against the employment of labor from [another] state.’”) (internal citation omitted). 209 Id. at 847 (noting that in United Building & Construction Trades Council v. City of Camden, 465 U.S. 208 (1984), the Court held that the local hiring ordinance “could violate the Privileges and Immunities Clause because it disadvantaged both in-state and out-of-state residents alike”). 206 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 52 “source of evil” at which the targeted hiring measures are properly aimed. C. Conflict of Targeted Hiring Measures with the Commerce Clause of Article I of the U.S. Constitution State or local laws that burden or discriminate against interstate or foreign commerce may be invalidated on the ground that they violate the dormant or negative Commerce Clause. “When a state statute directly regulates or discriminates against interstate commerce, or when its effect is to favor in-state economic interests over out-of-state interests, it will generally be struck down without further inquiry.”210 “When, however, a statute has only indirect effects on interstate commerce and regulates evenhandedly, a court should examine whether the state’s interest is legitimate and whether the burden on interstate commerce clearly exceeds the local benefits.”211 Targeted hiring measures that contain a preference for local residents may run afoul of the dormant Commerce Clause. In W.C.M. Window Co. v. Bernardi, the Seventh Circuit held that an Illinois statute requiring preference for Illinois residents in hiring for all public works projects violated the dormant Commerce Clause.212 The court observed that the statute had the same general effect on the flow into Illinois of labor services supplied by individuals unwilling to change their residence to Illinois at least a year before beginning to work in the state as an 210 Brown-Forman Distillers Corp. v. N.Y. State Liquor Auth., 476 U.S. 573, 579 (1986). 211 Id. The Ninth Circuit has opined, “[e]ven in the context of dormant commerce clause analysis, the Supreme Court has frequently admonished that courts should not second-guess the empirical judgments of lawmakers concerning the utility of legislation.” Pac. Nw. Venison Producers v. Smitch, 20 F.3d 1008, 1017 (9th Cir. 1994) (internal quotation omitted); see also Alaska Airlines, Inc. v. City of Long Beach, 951 F.2d 977, 983 (9th Cir. 1991) (“For a facially neutral statute to violate the commerce clause, the burdens of the statute must so outweigh the putative benefits as to make the statute unreasonable or irrational.”). 212 730 F.2d 486, 494 (7th Cir. 1984). BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 53 Illinois import tariff on coal would have on the flow of coal into the state.213 After concluding that the market participation exception was inapplicable, the Court held that the statute violated the dormant Commerce Clause, reasoning that the state had made no showing of actual or probable harm resulting from non-residents obtaining public works construction jobs.214 The Supreme Court has recognized a market participation exception to the application of the Commerce Clause.215 In White v. Mass. Council of Construction Employers, the Supreme Court considered a commerce clause challenge to an executive order by the Mayor of Boston,216 which required that all construction projects funded in whole or in part by city funds, or funds which the city had the authority to administer, should be performed by a work force consisting of at least half bona fide residents of Boston.217 With respect to projects funded wholly with city funds, the Court held that the city was acting as a market participant and therefore immune from challenge under 213 Id. Id. at 496. 215 See Reeves v. Stake, 447 U.S. 429, 436–37 (1980) (“The Commerce Clause responds principally to state taxes and regulatory measures impeding free private trade in the national marketplace. There is no indication of a constitutional plan to limit the ability of the States themselves to operate freely in the free market.” (internal citations omitted)). 216 The Executive Order specifically provided, “[o]n any construction project funded in whole or in part by City funds, or funds which, in accordance with a federal grant or otherwise, the City expends or administers, and to which the City is a signatory to the construction contract, the worker hours on a craft-by-craft basis shall be performed, in accordance with the contract documents established herewith, as follows: a. at least 50% by bona fide Boston residents; b. at least 25% by minorities; c. at least 10% by women.” Only the residency requirement was challenged in the case reviewed by the Court. White v. Mass. Council of Constr. Employers, 460 U.S. 204, 205 n.1 (1983). 217 Significantly, the Court found that, as a factual matter, none of the city’s funds had been used to partially finance private projects. Thus the Court limited its review to the propriety of applying the Mayor’s executive order to projects funded wholly with city funds and projects funded in part with federal funds. Id. at 209. 214 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 54 the Commerce Clause.218 The Court observed that the executive order covered “a discrete, identifiable class of economic activity in which the city is a major participant,” such that “[e]veryone affected by the order is, in a substantial if informal sense, ‘working for the city.’”219 States and localities wishing to apply targeted hiring measures to green construction projects assisted with federal Housing and Urban Development funds may also have some insulation against dormant Commerce Clause challenges. With respect to projects funded in part with federal funds, the Court in White opined that where state or local government action is specifically authorized by Congress, it is not subject to the Commerce Clause even if it interferes with interstate commerce.220 The Court examined applicable statutes related to the funding from the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development at issue221 and found that the funding was “intended to encourage economic revitalization, including improved opportunities for the poor, minorities, and unemployed.”222 The Court concluded that, “the Mayor’s executive order sounds a harmonious note; the federal regulations for each program affirmatively permit the type of parochial favoritism expressed in the order.”223 Thus, as with the Privileges and Immunities issue, policymakers have a number of ways to avoid a dormant 218 Id. at 214–15. Id. at 211, n.7. 220 Id. at 213 (citing Southern Pacific Co. v. Arizona, 325 U.S. 761, 769 (1945)). 221 The regulations provided that the city must “comply with . . . Section 3 of the Housing and Urban Development Act of 1968, as amended, and implementing regulations at 24 C.F.R. Part 135.” 24 C.F.R. § 570.458(c)(14)(ix)(D) (1982). The regulations implementing that Act provide that “to the greatest extent feasible opportunities for training and employment arising in connection with the planning and carrying out of any project assisted under any such program be given to lower income persons residing in the area of such project . . . .” 24 C.F.R. § 135.1(a)(2)(i) (1982). 222 White, 460 U.S. at 213. 223 Id. 219 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 55 Commerce Clause challenge. They may simply adopt targeted hiring measures that are not residency-based, or may adopt the Cleveland approach described above. Further, as one might expect would occur in many cases, the targeted hiring measure may properly be adopted as a part of market participation by the subject locality. D. Conflict of Targeted Hiring Measures with the Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment to the U.S. Constitution The Equal Protection Clause provides that no state shall “deny to any person within its jurisdiction the equal protection of the laws.”224 A strict scrutiny standard of review applies to government policies or laws that either (1) make distinctions on the basis of certain inherently suspect characteristics (such as race, ethnicity, national origin, and religion); or (2) restrict the exercise of certain “fundamental” rights (such as the right to vote or of access to the courts).225 If no suspect class or fundamental right is involved, however, the statute at issue is evaluated under a rational relationship test, and it is valid if “it rationally furthers some legitimate, articulated state purpose and therefore does not constitute an invidious discrimination in violation of the Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment.”226 Accordingly, targeted hiring measures that contain preferences based on inherently suspect characteristics such as race or ethnicity, if challenged, would likely be subject to strict scrutiny review and may be unlikely to survive in the absence of 224 U.S. CONST. amend. XIV, § 1. Plyler v. Doe, 457 U.S. 202, 216–17 (1982). If strict scrutiny is required, the state must demonstrate that the statute at issue is narrowly tailored to serve legitimate objectives and it is the least restrictive means of accomplishing these objectives. Id. 226 San Antonio Independent Sch. Dist. v. Rodriguez, 411 U.S. 1, 17 (1973). Under this standard, “[a] statutory discrimination will not be set aside if any state of facts reasonably may be conceived to justify it.” McGowan v. Maryland, 366 U.S. 420, 426 (1961). 225 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 56 a disparity study demonstrating past discrimination in the relevant market.227 Perhaps in part for this reason, few targeted hiring measures contain such preferences. Far more common among targeted hiring standards, but still implicating the Equal Protection clause, are preferences based on residency. Such measures are likely to survive an Equal Protection challenge. The Supreme Court has held that municipal laws establishing local residency requirements for city employment are subject to “rational basis” review under the Equal Protection Clause228 and that, under that lenient standard, such measures are constitutional.229 In Jersey City, the district court denied a motion for summary judgment by the party challenging on Equal Protection grounds the city ordinance requiring subsidized developers to employ city residents.230 The Court found that in the Equal Protection context, the right to pursue a particular line of employment is not a fundamental right231 and that non-residents do not constitute a suspect class.232 227 In Richmond v. J. A. Croson Co., the Supreme Court struck down a city-adopted plan that required prime contractors to whom the city awarded construction contracts to subcontract at least 30 percent of the dollar amount of the contract to one or more Minority Business Enterprises. 488 U.S. 469 (1989). The purpose of the plan was to promote wider participation by minority business enterprises in the construction of public projects. Id. at 470. Applying the two prongs of the strict scrutiny standard, the Court found that the evidence did not point to any identified discrimination in the construction industry. Id. at 471. The Court held that the city had failed to demonstrate a compelling governmental interest in apportioning public contracting opportunities on the basis of race or that its remedy had been narrowly tailored to the achievement of that interest. Id. at 470. 228 Mass. Bd. of Retirement v. Murgia, 427 U.S. 307, 313 (1976); see also Salem Blue Collar Workers Ass’n v. City of Salem, 33 F.3d 265, 271 (3d Cir. 1994). 229 McCarthy v. Philadelphia Civil Serv. Comm’n, 424 U.S. 645, 647 (1976); accord Salem Blue Collar Workers Ass’n v. City of Salem, 33 F.3d 265, 271 (3rd Cir. 1994). 230 Hudson Country Bldg. & Construction Trades Council v. City of Jersey City, 960 F. Supp. 823, 831 (D.N.J. 1996). 231 Id. (citing Oklahoma Educ. Ass’n v. Alcoholic Beverage Laws Enforcement Comm’n, 889 F.2d 929, 932 (10th Cir. 1989)). 232 Id. at 832. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 57 Applying a rational basis test, the court concluded that the asserted purpose of reducing unemployment among city residents was legitimate and held that a factual question remained as to whether the ordinance rationally furthered that purpose, such that summary judgment was improper.233 E. Conflict of Targeted Hiring Measures with Federal Highway Administration Competitive Bidding Statute and Regulations Policymakers seeking to adopt residency-based targeted hiring measures for projects funded by the Federal Highway Administration (“FHWA”) confront a special set of concerns. The federal statute governing funds administered by the FHWA provides that the Secretary of Transportation must “require such plans and specifications and such methods of bidding as shall be effective in securing competition.”234 The FHWA has promulgated regulations implementing this statutory provision that may create obstacles to residency-based targeted hiring measures: Title 23 C.F.R § 635.110(b) prohibits contract requirements for bonds and other features that might restrict competition; Title 23 C.F.R § 635.112(d) renders inapplicable to federal-aid projects bidding procedures that discriminate, inter alia, on the basis of national, state, or local boundaries;235 and 233 Id. 23 U.S.C.S. § 112(a) (2009); see also §112(b) (2009) (“[C]onstruction of each project . . . shall be performed by contract awarded by competitive bidding, unless the State transportation department demonstrates, to the satisfaction of the Secretary, that some other method is more cost effective or that an emergency exists. Contracts for the construction of each project shall be awarded only on the basis of the lowest responsive bid submitted by a bidder meeting established criteria of responsibility.”). 235 Title 23 C.F.R § 635.112(d) states: Nondiscriminatory bidding procedures shall be afforded to all qualified bidders regardless of National, State or local boundaries and without regard to race, color, religion, sex, national origin, age, or handicap. If any provisions of State laws, specifications, regulations, or policies may operate in any manner contrary to 234 BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 58 Title 23 C.F.R. § 635.117(b) bars contract requirements that discriminate against labor from other states or territories.236 The Sixth Circuit has held that the Cleveland residents’ preference ordinance discussed above does not violate § 635.117(b) because, by design, it does not discriminate against out-of-state residents.237 However, in a recent letter to the Mayor of Cleveland, the Secretary of Transportation determined that permitting an application of the Cleveland ordinance to FHWAfunded projects would be “inconsistent with the requirement to secure competition.”238 The Secretary reasoned that “mandatory local hiring preferences” in the ordinance would “discourage contractors who are not based in the Cleveland area from bidding” because they may have to hire and train a new workforce.239 Federal requirements, including title VI of the Civil Rights Act of 1964, to prevent submission of a bid, or prohibit consideration of a bid submitted by any responsible bidder appropriately qualified in accordance with § 635.110, such provisions shall not be applicable to Federal-aid projects. Where such nonapplicable provisions exist, notices of advertising, specifications, special provisions or other governing documents shall include a positive statement to advise prospective bidders of those provisions that are not applicable. Id. 236 Title 23 C.F.R § 635.117(b) (2009) states that “[n]o procedures or requirement shall be imposed by any State which will operate to discriminate against the employment of labor from any other State, possession or territory of the United States, in the construction of a Federal-aid project.” 237 City of Cleveland v. Ohio Dept. of Transport., 508 F.3d 827, 847 (6th Cir. 2007) (“Cleveland’s ordinance was drafted to avoid reaching contractors who hire only out-of-state workers, so it does not ‘discriminate against the employment of labor from [another] state.’ 23 C.F.R. § 635.117(b) (2009). The plain text of the regulation certainly prohibits much geographically-based discrimination, but it does not prohibit all such discrimination. Conspicuously absent from the list ‘State, possession or territory,’ is the phrase ‘or political subdivision,’ the word ‘locality,’ and any other such term that would express an intent to proscribe intrastate discrimination.”). 238 Letter from Ray LaHood, Sec’y of Transp., to Frank G. Jackson, Mayor of Cleveland (June 5, 2009)(on file with the author). 239 Id. BEACHFINAL.DOC 4/10/2010 2:42 PM USING GOVERNMENT POLICY 59 This reasoning seems excessively cautious given Cleveland’s modest requirement that a mere 20% of the workforce be made up of local residents, with out-of-state workers excluded from the calculation.240Moreover, any number of existing policies— including small business subcontracting or outreach requirements, certain bonding and insurance requirements, requirements related to supply chain or construction materials— might be said to inhibit competition by discouraging bidding by contractors to at least the degree that the Cleveland ordinance does. Notably, at least one court has managed to reconcile anticompetitive bidding measures with local policy requiring utilization of women and minority-owned businesses.241 And the effect of a modest targeted hiring program on contractors competing for work is arguably far more speculative than the effect of the MBE/WBE utilization requirements at issue in that case. Nevertheless, until the Agency is persuaded to change its “longstanding position” that “mandatory local hiring preferences” run afoul of the anti-competitive bidding provisions of the federal statute, policymakers would be well advised to avoid applying residency-based targeted hiring measures to projects funded with FHWA funds. As the analysis above reveals, while the legal considerations are several and not insubstantial, states and localities may adopt lawful Green Construction Careers measures as policy. States and localities may act with some assurance in adopting policies that squarely advance the subject locality’s proprietary interests. Further, with careful drafting properly tailored to the context, policymakers may safely address many of the legal issues discussed above. CONCLUSION As the concept of “green jobs” percolates through popular 240 See supra notes 205–06. See generally Domar Electric, Inc. v. City of Los Angeles, 885 P.2d 934 (1994). 241 BEACHFINAL.DOC 60 4/10/2010 2:42 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY consciousness, serious policymakers would do well to focus on the fundamental questions: What jobs do we wish to create?, Where? and For whom? With government initiatives rightly focused on the green construction sector, a number of best practices may be drawn from construction careers models, even though they may be recently developed. As the above policy examples and analysis of legal issues reveals, innovative and lawful Green Construction Careers measures are available to policymakers concerned with these questions. With the right combination of carefully constructed policies, the term “green jobs” may come to have real meaning in every corner of society, as noteworthy numbers of low-income and otherwise disadvantaged men and women embark on middle class green construction careers. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY: RENTAL STABILITY ALTERNATIVE By Arlo Chase* INTRODUCTION For more than 85 years, the United States government has promoted homeownership through mortgage programs, tax subsidies and popular rhetoric. The exhortations of homeownership became even more pronounced throughout the 1990s and this decade. President George W. Bush’s campaign for the “Ownership Society”1 represented the culmination of this *Associate Adjunct Professor of Law, Brooklyn Law School; Senior Vice President for Policy Initiatives, New York State Housing Finance Agency/State of New York Mortgage Agency. The opinions expressed herein are mine alone and do not represent those of my employers. I would like to thank the following people for their helpful comments and suggestions: Susanna Kohn, Oscar Chase, David Reiss, Christopher Serkin, Lee Ann Fennell, Robert Ellickson, Martin Kohn and Vicki Been. I would also like to thank the staff of The Journal of Law and Policy for their helpful editing. Moira Skeados provided able and much appreciated research assistance. 1 See, e.g., Robert J. Schiller, American Casino, ATLANTIC, Mar. 2005, available at http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/200503/shiller (detailing former President George W. Bush’s proposed “ownership society,” which planned to let people “own” their Social Security contributions, in the form of personal retirement accounts; “own” their health care, through portable health savings accounts; and own their homes in greater numbers, through bigger homeowner subsidies, noting that such proposals would encourage individual saving, but also increase the risk to which most American households would be subject); see also Greg Ip et al., Housing Bust Fuels Blame Game, WALL ST. J., Feb. 27, 2008 (quoting President George W. Bush as stating, as part of the “ownership society” that, “we want everybody in America to own their own home”). 61 CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 62 push for homeownership. While there are arguments to be made in favor of facilitating homeownership for qualified households, in recent decades such promotion went beyond qualified households and thereby helped fuel a housing bubble that ultimately burst, resulting in a severe economic recession and the foreclosure of millions of households. For the past 30 years, government programs and resources have largely ignored the other dominant tenure form—renting.2 This neglect of rental housing and rental households has helped create a troubling situation in which nearly half of all rental households spend more than the government recommends on housing,3 putting such households at risk of having insufficient resources for other necessities like food, medical care, transportation and education. The current housing crisis offers a historical opportunity to assess our national and local housing policies.4 In sum, the continued focus on homeownership, to the exclusion of renting, is in need of immediate revision. A policy shift is in order— government needs to direct immediate attention and increased resources to rental housing. Such a shift would belatedly acknowledge the fact that, notwithstanding the last eight decades 2 See, e.g., Clean Benson, Building a Better Public Housing Policy, CONG. Q. (July 17, 2009) available at http://www.cqpolitics.com/wmspage. cfm?parm1=1&docID=news-000003168984 at 1–2 (quoting Bruce Katz, stating that for the past eight years “[w]e had a really imbalanced housing policy, not just in the private sector, but in the public sector, toward homeownership”); see also Ip et al. supra note 1 (quoting Richard Styron, former CEO of Freddie Mac stating “[w]e went crazy as a country with the goals, saying everybody’s got to have a house”) (internal quotation marks omitted). 3 See infra Section IV.AB. 4 See, e.g., Robert J. Shiller, A Time for Bold Thinking on Housing, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 25, 2007, at 4 (arguing that the current housing price downturn indicates a need for innovation in housing, including better management of risk); Press Release, Nat’l Found. for Credit Counseling, Survey Reveals Long-Term Implications of Mortgage Meltdown (June 23, 2009), available at http://www.nfcc.org/NewsRoom/newsreleases/files09/ HomeownershipSurvey.pdf (finding that popular attitudes about benefits of homeownership have changed dramatically in the wake of the foreclosure crisis). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 63 and hundreds of billions of dollars encouraging and subsidizing homeownership, almost one third of the households in the U.S. currently rent, and at least 95% of all Americans rent at some point in their lives.5 Specifically, additional resources and programs are needed which promote opportunities for increased rental stability and affordability. The need for these changes is evidenced by (i) the excess demand for rental housing compared with supply which has resulted in the affordability crisis for so many rental households;6 and (ii) the number of households that have overstretched their budgets in order to buy homes they could not afford, often because the rental options available to them were simply not stable and/or affordable enough.7 To address this increasingly untenable situation, I propose a rental stability program that would offer tenants an option for longer lease terms, rights to lease renewal, temporary regulation of rent increases, and federal rental subsidies to cover rent increases for rent-burdened low and moderate income households.8 My proposal is essentially a modest one that provides renters with additional opportunities for stable tenancy and time limited price protection, while maintaining marketbased incentives for owners to create new rental housing units and maintain existing ones. A brief review of our current national housing policy— provided in Part I of this article—will set the stage for the reforms urged herein. I rely on existing literature for both Part I and Part II, in which I examine the extraordinary societal 5 See Bruce Katz & Margery Austin Turner, Rethinking U.S. Rental Housing Policy, BROOKINGS INSTITUTION, 2007 http://www.brookings.edu/ papers/2007/0228metropolitanpolicy_katz_Opp08.aspx; see also WILLIAM APGAR, RETHINKING RENTAL HOUSING: EXPANDING THE ABILITY OF RENTAL HOUSING TO SERVE AS A PATHWAY TO ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL OPPORTUNITY 1 (Dec. 2004) http://www.jchs.harvard.edu/publications/markets/w04-11.pdf [hereinafter “Apgar 2004”]. 6 See infra Section IV.A. 7 See infra Section IV.B. 8 See, e.g., Lee Anne Fennell, Homeownership 2.0, 102 NW. U. L. REV 1047, 1059 (2008) (“Longer and better leaseholds and reform of homeownership’s tax advantages are worthy goals . . . .”). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 64 benefits afforded to promote homeownership and the reasons typically given for them. I discuss several poignant studies that raise serious concerns about the degree to which U.S. policies promoting homeownership actually serve the stated goals of household and neighborhood stability. Currently, it must be acknowledged, the immensity of the homeownership subsidies provided is matched only by the immensity of the devastation wrought on individual households and surrounding communities by the current foreclosure crisis. In Part II, I integrate the findings of several housing studies to argue that the goals underlying the homeownership push can be met equally by enhanced rental stability. In Part III, I briefly review the enormously destabilizing effects of the foreclosure crisis on both individuals and communities. This leads into what I consider to be my real contribution to the existing literature: Part IV in which I lay out the factual case for expending more government resources and creating new legal protections for renters. Part V details the components of my proposed rental stability program and a discussion of how it serves my goal. That goal is to create increased opportunities for renters to obtain some meaningful measure of security in their tenure while avoiding excessive distortions in the rental market. I also evaluate the likely effects of my proposed program and respond to some likely critiques. Finally, in Part VI I examine three distinct recent policy proposals to addressing the housing crisis. I. U.S. HOUSING POLICY IS SKEWED TO HOMEOWNERSHIP A. History Since the Great Depression, our national housing policy has been primarily aimed at increasing homeownership.9 These 9 See, e.g., Anthony Downs, Why Rental Housing Is the Neglected Child of American Shelter in RETHINKING RENTAL HOUSING 78 (2008) [hereinafter Downs, Why]; see also ALEX F. SCHWARTZ, HOUSING POLICY IN THE UNITED STATES 48 (2006); Rachel D. Godsil & David V. Simunovich, CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 65 efforts included the development of the Federal Housing Administration (FHA) and U.S. Department of Veterans Affairs (VA) homeownership loan programs, which guarantee up to 90% of the value of a home as collateral for loans from private banks.10 Another Depression Era creation, the Federal National Mortgage Association, more commonly known as Fannie Mae, began in 1968 to offer similar mortgage guarantees to a broader cross section of Americans.11 In 1990 the Federal Home Mortgage Corporation, otherwise known as Freddie Mac, began to offer similar products as those of Fannie Mae.12 Given their hybrid status as government created but privately owned corporations, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are known collectively as Government Sponsored Enterprises, or GSEs.13 Perhaps more important than the mortgage insurance offered by FHA, VA and the GSEs, these entities introduced and standardized many aspects of the mortgage industry that we now take for granted, such as the 30 year self-amortizing mortgage, the standardized appraisal process and the reduction of the downpayment required to 10% or lower.14 These advances, combined with significant economic growth in the post WWII Protecting Status: The Mortgage Crisis, Eminent Domain and the Ethic of Homeownership, 77 FORDHAM L. REV 949, 956–57 (2008) (“[The] high rate of homeownership is largely a product of the federal government’s decision . . . to subsidize homeownership for the middle class.”). 10 See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 50; Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 957–58. 11 See David Reiss, The Federal Government’s Implied Guarantee of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac’s Obligations: Uncle Sam Will Pick Up the Tab, 42 GA. L. REV. 1019, 1030 (2008). 12 See id. at 1029 (“[Fannie Mae’s and Freddie Mac’s] purchasing practices have since converged.”). 13 See Reiss, supra note 11, at n.22 (“The term GSE refers to a federally chartered, privately owned, privately managed financial institution that has only specialized lending and guarantee powers and that bond market investors perceive as implicitly backed by the federal government.”) (internal citations and quotation marks omitted). 14 See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 5051; see also KENNETH JACKSON, CRABGRASS FRONTIER: THE SUBURBANIZATION OF THE UNITED STATES 20318 (1987). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 66 years, were extremely successful in increasing homeownership in this country. Between 1940 and 1970, the percentage of American homeowners increased from 44% to 65% of all households.15 Between 1970 and 1990 that rate stayed substantially the same, but then increased to over 67% by 2000 and 69% at the end of 2004.16 With the foreclosure crisis beginning in 2006, the homeownership rate has been contracting from the previous highs and by the middle of 2009 was at 67.4%.17 The reduction from 69% to 67.4% of all households may sounds small, but it represents over two million households.18 Notably, this represents the first significant decline in homeownership since the 1930’s.19 B. Homeownership Subsidies In addition to the federal mortgage programs discussed above, which are aimed at increasing the availability of home financing, federal and state governments provide a number of other direct and indirect financial benefits to homeowners. Most significantly, homeowners are entitled to deduct from the income on which they have to pay income taxes both the amount they 15 Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 957 n.22. Gale et al., Encouraging Homeownership Through the Tax Code, 115 TAX NOTES 1171 (2007). 17 See U.S. Census Bureau News, Census Bureau Reports on Residential Vacancies and homeownership, July 24, 2009, at 4, http://www.census.gov/ hhes/www/housing/hvs/qtr209/filesq209press.pdf; see also Kathleen M. Howley, U.S. Home Vacancies Hit 18.7 Million on Bank Seizures, BLOOMBERG.COM, July 24, 2009, http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid +20601206&sid=ajlP7ROLo39w (describing that the homeownership rate had dropped to 67.3%); John Leland, Homeownership Losses are Greatest Among Minorities, Report Finds, N.Y. TIMES, May 13, 2009, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2009/05/13/us/13homeowner.html. 18 See US Census Bureau Web Page, America’s Families and Living Arrangements: 2008: Table H1—Households by Type and Tenure of Householder for Selected Characteristics: 2008, Feb. 25, 2009, http://www.census.gov/population/www/socdemo/hh-fam/cps2008.html (estimating total number of American households). 19 See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 14 fig. 2.2. 16 CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 67 pay in real property taxes20 and interest paid on a mortgage secured by a personal residence.21 The mortgage interest deduction includes second homes in addition to primary residences, with an overall limit for each taxpayer of mortgages totaling up to $1 million.22 Other tax benefits include the fact that imputed rental income is not considered income for tax purposes and therefore is not taxed.23 Furthermore, in 1996 the tax code was amended at the initiation of the Clinton Administration so that homeowners selling their primary residence could exclude the first $250,000 of gain ($500,000 for married couples) from their reported income.24 Acknowledging all of these benefits to homeowners, two law professors conclude that “[h]omeowners are afforded both significant monetary benefits and social capital that renters are denied.”25 Scholars have identified a number of problems with the mortgage interest deduction and other federal tax benefits provided to homeowners. First, the current subsidies accrue disproportionately to households in higher income brackets.26 20 26 U.S.C. § 164(a) (2009). 26 U.S.C. §§ 163(h), 164 (2000). 22 See id. 23 Imputed rent is a tax concept that refers to the amount of rental income that the housing unit would generate if it were rented out. Imputed rent is taxed in a number of countries, such as Italy, Norway, and Denmark. See Fennell, supra note 8, at 1058 n.42 (citing sources); see also James R. Follain & Lisa Sturman Melamed, The False Messiah of Tax Policy: What Elimination of the Home Mortgage Interest Deduction Promises and a Careful Look at What it Delivers, 9 J. HOUSING RES. 179 (1998) (discussing importance of nontaxation of imputed rent). 24 26 U.S.C. § 121. This tax advantage can be claimed only once every two years, and certain limited conditions must be met regarding the ownership and use of the home. See Vikas Bajaj & David Leonhardt, Tax Break May Have Helped Cause Housing Bubble, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 19, 2008 (describing how this tax advantage coincided, and may have helped cause the incredible run up in housing prices from 1997–2006). 25 Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 953. 26 See, e.g., Gale et al., supra note 16, at 9 (describing the deduction as “upside down”); SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 72–76; Downs, Why, supra note 9, at 910. 21 CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 68 Deductions increase in value as a household’s taxable income increases, so that higher-income taxpayers in the 28 percent marginal tax bracket save 28 cents for every dollar of mortgage interest deduction, and lower income taxpayers in the 15 percent marginal tax bracket saves 15 cents for every dollar of mortgage interest deduction. As a result, in 2005 wealthy households (earning more than $200,000 per year) took more than eight times as much mortgage interest deduction than middle class households (earning between $50-75,000).27 Also, more significantly, homeowners who do not itemize their taxes do not benefit at all from the mortgage interest and real property tax deductions. Because many choose to take the standard deduction, only half of all homeowners benefit from these crucial government subsidies.28 Furthermore, other borrowers (such as credit card borrowers) are not entitled to deduct interest expenditures at all.29 The total annual cost to the federal government, in terms of tax expenditures and indirect subsidies of the GSEs, is in the $150 to $200 billion range annually. Even without the benefits provided through the GSEs and FHA and VA, which are difficult to quantify,30 the tax revenue lost annually to 27 See Gale et al., supra note 16, at 910. See Roger Lowenstein, Tax Break: Who Needs the Mortgage Interest Deduction, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 5, 2006. 29 The Tax Reform Act of 1986 eliminated the deductibility of other kinds of interest payments, including credit cards, pushing more homeowners into increasing their mortgages. See Lowenstein, supra note 28. 30 The actual subsidy to the GSEs prior to 2008 was difficult to quantify because most of the subsidy was the implicit federal guarantee of the GSEs’ obligations, which in turn allowed them to access capital at a cheaper cost. Compare Gale et al., supra note 16, at 1777 (noting that to the extent it can be quantified, the Congressional Budget Office estimated subsidy to GSEs at $23 billion in 2003) with Reiss, supra note 11, at 104849 (noting that a Federal Reserve researcher “has estimated that the present value of the federal government’s subsidy of Fannie and Freddie is nearly $150 billion . . .”). In September 2008, the US Treasury Department announced that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were in danger of falling into insolvency and would be placed into conservatorship, governed by the newly created Federal Housing Finance Agency. See James R. Hagerty et al., U.S. Seizes 28 CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 69 homeownership benefits was in excess of $155 billion for 2006,31 over $125 billion for 2007 and approximately $230 billion in 2009.32 It is far from clear how we as a society benefit from these subsidies. Many economists believe that the tax benefits simply push up the price of homes and do not increase the levels of homeownership.33 Professor Schwartz of the New School notes that homeownership rates in the United State are comparable to those in Canada, Australia and several European countries, despite the fact that none of those countries subsidize homeownership nearly as much as the U.S.34 Most notably, none of those countries provide for the deductibility of mortgage interest or property taxes. In addition to having a dubious impact on the rate of homeownership, the tax incentives encourage Mortgage Giants, WALL ST. J., Sept. 8, 2008, at A1. While the Treasury initially pledged $100 billion, it was quickly raised to $200 billion to cover the losses of Fannie and Freddie. As of the date of this article that amount has been increased to $400 billion [on source], with close to $85 billion already distributed. See Chris Isidore, Fannie & Freddie: The Most Expensive Bailout, CNNMONEY.COM, July 22, 2009, http://money.cnn.com/2009/07/ 22/news/companies/fannie_freddie_bilout/index/htm. 31 See, e.g., Gale et al., supra note 16, at 1174. This includes approximately $30 billion in benefits accumulated from the non-taxation of imputed rent, as well as the deductibility of mortgage interest, property taxes and the exclusion from capital gains of sales proceeds. 32 See Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 958 (regarding 2007). It is unclear if this calculation includes the value of the non-taxation of imputed rent). In Housing Bust, Government Increasingly Favors Homeowners Over Renters, WALL ST. J., Nov. 17, 2009 (compared with $60 billion in aid to renters for 2009). 33 See, e.g., Gale et al., supra note 16, at 1180 (“[T]ime series evidence in the U.S. provides little reason to believe that the [mortgage interest deduction] has a substantial influence on homeownership.”); Steven Malanga, Obsessive Housing Disorder, CITY J., Spring 2009, at 10, available at http://www.city-journal.org/2009/19_2_homeownership.html (suggesting elimination of the mortgage interest deduction); Edward Glaeser & Joseph Gyourko, Two Ways to Revamp U.S Housing Policy, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 16, 2008, http://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2008/12/16/two-ways-torevamp-us -housing-policy/. 34 See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 76; see also Gale et al., supra note 16, at 118183. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 70 homeowners to buy more expensive houses and borrow more (up to $1 million), thereby increasing their tax deductions. These incentives are perverse in two ways: (i) they encourage homeowners to over-leverage their properties; and (ii) they encourage bigger and generally speaking more energy consumptive housing.35 The critiques of the mortgage interest deduction come from all sides of the political spectrum, including liberal housing scholars like William Apgar,36 more conservative housing economists from the American Enterprise Institute37 and the Manhattan Institute,38 economists from the Brookings Institute and MIT39 and an economic columnist from the New York 40 Times. While the effect of eliminating the mortgage interest deduction is debated,41 along with what should replace it, these 35 See Andre F. Shashaty, Help Us Shape the Future of Affordable Housing Policy, AFFORDABLE HOUSING FINANCE, Mar. 2008, at 24 (quoting Brett Harvey). 36 See Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 5–9. 37 See EDWARD GLAESER & JOSEPH GYOURKO, RETHINKING FEDERAL HOUSING POLICY: HOW TO MAKE HOUSING PLENTIFUL AND AFFORDABLE (AEI Press, 2008) (proposing that the mortgage interest deduction be substantially reduced to a cap of $300,000 in large portions of the country that restrict housing through local zoning and land use regulations). But see Letter from Charles McMillan, President, Nat’l Assoc. of Realtors, to President Obama (Feb. 26, 2009) (“The National Association of REALTORS® believe the [Mortgage Interest Deduction] is the single most important tax provision for our nation and our families.”) 38 See Steven Malanga, Obsessive Housing Disorder, CITY J., Spring 2009 at 10. 39 See Gale et al., supra note 16. 40 See Lowenstein, supra note 28. 41 See Follain & Melamed, supra note 23, at 19596 (arguing that the elimination of the mortgage interest deduction might not produce the predicted effects of equalizing the tax treatment of higher and lower income households, since higher income households might be able to finance their home purchases through other means like cash purchases and noting that the nontaxation of imputed rent might be more important to address than the mortgage interest deduction). Cf. Gale et al., supra note 16, at 16–17 (arguing that eliminating the mortgage interest deduction will increase investment in rental properties, but will also encourage owners to sink more CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 71 critiques have made it into reform proposals. For example, in 2005 President Bush’s Bipartisan Advisory Panel on Federal Tax Reform proposed changing the mortgage interest deduction to a 15 percent credit and making it available to all tax filers, regardless of itemization status.42 President Obama proposed a similar plan during his campaign.43 As with other plans to restrict or amend the mortgage interest deduction, neither proposal has gathered momentum in Congress. Still, other changes have been proposed. President Obama’s fiscal year 2010–11 budget proposal advanced the idea of reducing the rate of mortgage and other deductions available to taxpayers in the highest tax brackets.44 This budget proposal did not pass however, as the National Association of Realtors and other real estate interest groups responded with their usual predictions of disaster if such a change were enacted.45 II. WHY DO WE SPEND ALL THIS MONEY TO SUPPORT HOMEOWNERSHIP? In the midst of the great depression, President Franklin Roosevelt argued that, “special safeguards should be thrown around home ownership as a guarantee of social and economic stability.”46 But that begs the question. Assuming for a moment that the various homeownership subsidies outlined above actually equity into their homes and thus may end up in increasing total investment in housing). 42 See Lowenstein, supra note 28, at 45. 43 See Nick Timiraos, Homeownership Push is Rethought, WALL ST. J., Sept. 12, 2008 (“Senator Obama has proposed a 10% mortgage interest tax credit for homeowners who don’t itemize.”). 44 See OFFICE OF MANAGEMENT AND BUDGET, A NEW ERA OF RESPONSIBILITY: RENEWING AMERICA’S PROMISE 29–30 (2009), available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/assets/fy2010_new_era/A_New_Era_of_Res ponsibility2.pdf. 45 See Press Release, Nat’l Ass’n of Realtors, NAR Opposes Mortgage Interest Deduction Provision on Obama’s Budget Proposal, (Feb. 26, 2009), available at http://www.realtor.org/government_affairs/mortgage_interest_ deduction/mid_obama_budget_proposal. 46 See Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 985 n.168. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 72 do increase the rate of homeownership, there still remains the question of why our society should spend all these resources to privilege homeownership over renting. The main reasons proffered for supporting homeownership are: (i) homeownership benefits individual households; and (ii) an increase in homeownership creates positive externalities, or positive spillover effects that are shared by the community surrounding the homeowner households. A. Homeownership Benefits Individuals We can further divide the first claim—that households benefit from homeownership—into two basic components. The first is that enabling households to purchase homes will benefit those households financially.47 The financial benefit is also multifaceted. First, by having to make mortgage payments and thereby gaining equity, homeownership “gives households a default mechanism for savings.”48 That increased equity, in turn, “permits the owner to leverage capital, which can help to buy investment properties, start a new business, send a child to college, or save for retirement.”49 In addition to promoting savings and enabling households increased access to capital, homeowners enjoy a measure of price protection against housing cost increases that enable them to better plan financially.50 Of course the price protections are not absolute: real estate taxes, insurance and homeowners association or cooperative/condominium dues may increase, as may borrowing costs of borrowers who have taken out adjustable rate or 51 payment option mortgages. But, at least compared with renters 47 But see Nat’l Found. For Credit Counseling, supra note 4 (finding that “almost half of all American adults, more than 100 million people, no longer believe that homeownership is a realistic way to build wealth”). 48 See Shelter or Burden? ECONOMIST, Apr. 16, 2009 (quoting Richard Green of the University of South Carolina). 49 See Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 954. 50 See Fennell, supra note 8, at 1054–55 (discussing price protection and caveats). 51 See id. at 1055. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 73 who are subject to market based rent increases on annual intervals, most homeowners’ housing costs are more predictable. Scholars also attribute increased stability to 52 homeownership. This is related to price stability, of course, but the notion is somewhat broader than just price. The argument is that homeowners enjoy a psychic benefit resulting from their property rights to exercise dominion over their homes, exclude outsiders, and to remain in perpetuity (subject, of course, to the rights of lenders and governments to foreclose for non-payment of mortgages or taxes).53 Furthermore, as Professors Godsil & 52 While most scholars identify increased stability as a positive effect, there is some debate. Compare Apgar 2004 at 41–42 (“[R]esidential stability not only appears to promote community involvement and development of beneficial social capital but also effects educational outcomes.”) with Ingrid Ellen & Brendan O’Flaherty How New York Housing Policies Are Different— And Maybe Why, in THE WELFARE STATE IN NEW YORK CITY (Irwin Garfinkel and Marcia Meyers eds., Russell Sage Foundation (forthcoming 2010), at 33 (“While stability may be good for neighbors and for children, subsidizing it can create deadweight losses. Mobility gets workers to where they are most productive.”); see also Robert C. Ellickson, The Mediocrity of Government Subsidies to Mixed-Income Housing Projects, 16–17 & n.28 (Yale Law & Economics Research Paper No. 360, 2008), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1217870 [hereinafter Ellickson, The Mediocrity] (discussing mixed results of lock in effect resulting from rent regulation and project based subsidies); Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at n.100 (noting negative effect on the efficiency of labor markets resulting from housing stability; see also Sam Roberts, Slump Creates Lack of Mobility for Americans, N.Y. TIMES, Apr. 22, 2009 (Census Bureau has found that fewer people are moving in the recessionary economy, creating fears that jobrelated moves are getting suppressed and workers are not re-sorted to the jobs that best use their skills). See Generally Robert C. Ellickson, Legal Constraints on Households Moves: Should Footloose Americans Envy the Rooted French, 6 n.8 (Yale Law & Economics Research Paper No. 300, 2009) available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1445603 [hereinafter Ellickson, Legal Constraints] (reviewing differences in moving patterns among countries and discussing normative questions of which is preferable). 53 See Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 954–56 (citing psychological benefits of homeownership); see also Gale et al., supra note 16, at 1171 (“Owning one’s home is widely viewed as an integral part of the American Dream . . . Americans are taught from an early age to aspire to homeownership . . . .”); Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 56 (“Residential CHASE REVISED.DOC 74 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY Simunovich write, once a down payment has been made and a mortgage obtained, “the household tends to be less mobile because the transaction costs associated with moving have been increased. This reduced mobility . . . translates into both commitment to place and stability for family.”54 And, for children, “[i]n the educational arena, residential stability helps students avoid the disruption linked to the relocation from one school to another.”55 In sum, scholars find a number of positive effects for households who achieve residential stability. B. External Benefits of Homeownership The positive community benefits associated with increased homeownership are well summarized by Gale et al: [m]ost importantly, homeowners may be more likely to be active citizens working for long-term, communitywide benefits. Homeowners may also take better care of their houses than renters would. High rates of homeownership may reduce crime in the area, perhaps because the greater geographic stability of homeowners vs. renters means that someone committing a crime would be recognized. Any of these behaviors, if sufficiently prevalent, could plausibly raise property values in the community at large and hence provide a benefit to people other than the homeowner.56 The general theory posits that the value of homes are so dependent on the health of their surrounding community that stability also enables parents to develop deeper and more meaningful attachment to social support networks, and to access existing job and human service referral networks.”). 54 Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 971–72. 55 See Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 41 (citing Eric A. Hanushek et al., Disruption Versus Tiebout Improvement: The Costs and Benefits of Switching Schools, 88 J. PUB. ECON. 1721–46 (2004)). 56 See Gale et al., supra note 16, at 6; see also Fennell, supra note 8, at 1098–99, n.209 & n.213; Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 970 (“A range of empirical studies have concluded that homeownership does in fact have salutary benefits for households and communities . . . .”). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 75 homeowners have a strong self interest in improving and maintaining their neighborhoods.57 C. The Reasons for Supporting Homeownership Argue Equally For Enhanced Rental Stability Many of the arguments supporting homeownership follow from the claim that homeownership is a more stable form of tenure than renting. But there is no reason to think that the positive effects for individual households and surrounding communities associated with the stability offered by homeownership are restricted to homeownership. As Apgar states, while “the social/psychological aspects of housing are discussed in terms of owner-occupied housing . . . there is nothing inherent in the concept of ‘home’ that is necessarily linked to homeownership.”58 And there is empirical support for 57 Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9 at 972 (“Once a homeowner has developed a financial stake in a particular dwelling, there is a close link between that financial stake and the well-being of the community in which the dwelling is located.”); see WILLIAM A. FISCHEL, THE HOMEVOTER HYPOTHESIS 9–12 (2001) (arguing that homeowners are so concerned about property values that they become risk averse to a fault, making homeowners into “NIMBYs” even when a proposed change carries a positive expected value). There is, however, substantial debate concerning whether increased homeownership is merely correlated with these benefits or whether it in fact causes such outcomes. See Fennell, supra note 8, at n.213 (“Selection bias presents a difficulty in interpreting empirical results, however—do people with good-neighbor characteristics just happen to become homeowners, or is there something about homeownership that improves their neighborliness.”). Gale et al., conclude that, “while there are some compelling arguments in theory for external benefits from homeownership, there is little evidence in practice to support those arguments. That does not prove that the arguments are wrong, but the burden should be on advocates of homeownership subsidies to make the case, and that case has not yet been made in a compelling fashion.” See Gale et al., supra note 16, at 7; see also Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 4 (“[P]olicy makers are often less than cautious in interpreting the existing literature [regarding benefits of homeownership].”). 58 See Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 15; see also Ellen & O’Flaherty, supra note 52, at 33 (“To the extent that rent control and rent subsidies mean that tenants realize consumer surplus from their apartments in New York, CHASE REVISED.DOC 76 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY this assertion: a much cited study from two leading housing economists finds that much of the positive spillover effect associated with increased homeownership in fact results from longer term residences, and not homeownership per se.59 This finding is supported by a research report from the National Association of Realtors, one of the biggest proponents of homeownership subsidies.60 The findings of this study make intuitive sense. Long-term tenants have the same interest as owners in living in clean and safe neighborhoods with good schools. Thus, long-term tenants are similarly likely to be engaged in civic affairs. While it is true that renters do not have the same profit motive as homeowners in creating desirable living conditions, it is they have a stake in the outcome of local political decisions, and so are more likely to participate intelligently in the development of those policies. This argument is usually made for homeownership [citing sources], but if it is true, then rent control and rent subsidies provide the same sort of advantages.”); see also id at 31 (“Both rent control and subsidies to singlefamily owners help to further population stability.”); Margaret Jane Radin, Property and Personhood, 34 STAN. L. REV. 957, 959 (1982) (“[T]enancy, no less than a single-family house, is the sort of property interest in which a person becomes self-invested; and after the self-investment has taken place, retention of the interest becomes a priority claim over curtailment of merely fungible interests of others.”). 59 Denise DiPasquale & Edward L. Glaeser, Incentives and Social Capital: Are Homeowners Better Citizens?, 45 J. URB. ECON., 354–84, (1999). 60 See Kristen David Adams, Homeownership: American Dream or Illusion of Empowerment?, 60 S.C. L. REV. 573, 591 & n.91 (2009) [hereinafter Adams, Homeownership] (quoting from Research Div., Nat’l Ass’n of Realtors, Social Benefits of Homeownership and Stable Housing (2006)), http://www.realtor.org/research/research/homeownershipbenefits (click “Social Benefits of Homeownership and Stable Housing” hyperlink) (“[T]he purported benefits of homeownership may partly arise not directly from the ownership, but from greater housing stability and social ties associated with less frequent movements among homeowners. Therefore, policies to boost homeownership can raise positive social outcomes, but only to the extent that homeownership brings housing stability. Also, if it is in fact the case that housing stability matters more than homeownership in bringing social benefits, then the policy implication is not necessarily to promote homeownership but to assist in residential stability.”). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 77 unreasonable to say the lack of such a motive would eliminate the desire to live in good conditions for one’s family.61 Indeed, one notable scholar, William Simon, argues that the increased stability achieved by rent control in fact encourages more robust long-term community involvement than homeownership because it forces the tenant to stay in place to share the benefits of community improvement, rather than enabling the resident to benefit from those improvements by selling their home at a premium.62 These studies suggest that a housing policy seeking to strengthen residential stability should encourage longer term stays in both owned homes and rentals. This would mean focusing on increasing “sustainable” homeownership, as well as increasing rental stability. This is the focus of my paper. Now we turn briefly to measure our current level of residential stability. In sum, the foreclosure crisis has had a devastating impact on the stability of millions of American households, their neighborhoods, and state and local governments. The devastation wrought by this crisis belies the notion that home ownership always promotes social and economic stability.63 61 For the reasons identified above, I believe that Lawrence Summers, the head of the President Obama’s Council of Economic Advisors is wrong to compare renting a home to renting a car. See Conor Dougherty, In the Exurbs, the American Dream Is Up for Rent, WALL ST. J., Mar. 31, 2009, at A18. (attributing to Laurence Summers the following statement: “No one in the history of the world ever washed a rental car”). My rejoinder is that many people wash leased cars that they have for one year, which is more akin to rental housing than renting a car for a weekend. Renting a car for a weekend is better analogized to renting a hotel room for a weekend, which I would agree, rarely gets cleaned by its occupants. 62 William H. Simon, Social-Republican Property, 38 UCLA L. REV. 1335, 1360 (1991); see also Benjamin D. Barros, Home as a Legal Concept, SANTA CLARA L. REV. 225, 290 n.147 (discussing the Simon article and economic and moral arguments involved in rent regulation). 63 See Shelter or Burden?, ECONOMIST, Apr. 16, 2009 (“[P]erversely, the decade of obsession with homeownership may actually have reduced neighborhood stability.”). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 78 III. THE FORECLOSURE CRISIS AND RESULTING INSTABILITY A. Foreclosure Crisis: The Statistics It was distressing to learn recently that, despite some stabilization in home prices,64 the increase in foreclosures has not abated. 65 In fact, the first six months of 2009 were the worst on record. New foreclosure filings reached over 1.5 million for the first half of 2009 according to RealtyTrac, the highest since it began recording in 2005.66 A report issued by the Mortgage Bankers Association on August 20, 2009 found that the combined percentage of loans in foreclosure and those otherwise delinquent was over 13% of all mortgages outstanding (more than one in eight loans), “the highest ever recorded in the MBA delinquency survey,” which commenced in its current form in 64 See David Streitfeld, Housing Perks Up, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 26, 2009, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2009/08/26/business/economy/26econ. html?_r=1&sep+1&sq=housing%20perks%20up&st=cse (citing CaseSchiller index report showing modest increases in housing prices in June 2009 in 18 of the 20 major U.S. metropolitan areas). 65 The detailed causes of the foreclosure crisis have been much discussed and debated. Neither of the thesis points in this paper, that our homeownership policies have not resulted in a stable housing situation and that a focus on rental housing is needed, are contingent on identifying the exact causes and culprits. However, I do believe the causes are complex and involve the following intertwined phenomenon: (i) the development of an overheated secondary market for funding mortgage loans, (ii) the creation of more exotic, complex and risky loan products that were designed for subprime borrowers but were soon pushed on all borrowers; (iii) an unparalleled run up in home prices; (iv) Americans taking out more and bigger mortgage loans and home equity loans throughout the late 1990s and early 2000; and finally (v) a severe economic recession and resulting job losses. See generally Adams, supra note 60, at 599–607 (discussing above mentioned causes of the foreclosure crisis); Raymond H. Brescia, Part of the Disease or Part of the Cure: The Financial Crisis and the Community Reinvestment Act, 60 S.C. L. REV. 617, 618, 620–27 (providing statistics on the subprime mortgage crisis). 66 See Les Christie, 1.5 million homes in foreclosure in ‘09, CNNMONEY.COM, July 16, 2009 http://money.cnn.com/2009/07/16/real_ estate/RealtyTrac_foreclosure_report/. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 79 1972.67 Notably, the foreclosure problems are increasingly affecting prime borrowers who have lost their jobs, as opposed to the 2006–2008 foreclosures which primarily affected those with subprime and/or adjustable rate loans.68 Experts predict that in 2009, 2.4 million homes will be lost to foreclosure or short sales.69 Another 1.7 million homes were foreclosed in 2008.70 Overall, between 2009–2012, Credit Suisse estimates that between 8 and 9 million homes will be foreclosed.71 And many of these homes, once foreclosed, are lying dormant. In July 2009 the US Census Bureau estimated that more than 10% of all homes were vacant.72 The foreclosure crisis demonstrates one of the downsides of the constant push for homeownership. By creating incentives for borrowers to incur more and more mortgage debt and shielding the profits from capital gains tax, federal housing policy 67 See Press Release, Mortgage Bankers Association, Delinquencies Continue to Climb, Foreclosures Flat in Latest MBA National Delinquency Survey, (Aug. 20, 2009), available at http://www.mortgagebankers.org/ NewsandMedia/PressCenter/70050.htm. 68 See Peter Goodman & Jack Healy, Job Losses Push Safer Mortgages to Foreclosure, N.Y. TIMES, May 24, 2009, at A1; Nick Timiraos, Souring Prime Loans Compound Mortgage Woes, WALL ST. J., Aug. 21, 2009, at A4. “Subprime” mortgages are intended “for borrowers with significant credit history problems.” SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 234 (internal quotation marks omitted). 69 Center for Responsible Lending, Subprime Spillover: Accelerating Foreclosures to Cost Neighbors $502 Billon in 2009 Alone, May 7, 2009, http://www.responsiblelending.org/mortgage-lending/research-analysis/ soaring-spillover-accelerating-foreclosures-to-cost-neighbors-436-billion-in2009-alone-73–4-million-homes-lose-5-900-on-average.html. 70 Simon, Banks Ramp Up Foreclosures, WALL ST. J., Apr. 15, 2009, at A1 (citing estimates available at http://www.economy.com). 71 Rod Dubitsky et al., Foreclosure Update: Over 8 Million Foreclosures Expected, CREDIT SUISSE, Dec. 4, 2008, at 1. 72 See U.S. Census Bureau News, supra note 17, at 1; see also Haya El Nasser, Open House, Anyone? 1 in 9 Homes Sit Empty, USA TODAY, Apr. 10, 2009; cf. John Leland, With Advocates Help, More Squatters Are Calling Foreclosures Home, N.Y. TIMES, Apr. 10, 2009, at A1 (describing growing phenomenon in Philadelphia, Minnesota, Miami, where organized grassroots efforts are placing homeless persons in foreclosed or abandoned homes). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 80 distorted the housing market and contributed to the real estate bubble and subsequent crash. The millions of foreclosures have had a devastating effect on the affected households, their surrounding neighborhoods, and local governments.73 These effects are reviewed below, beginning with individual households. B. Resulting Instability 1. Foreclosure Effects on Individuals At its core, foreclosure leaves a family without a place to live and increases the risk of homelessness. On a financial level, foreclosure results in the loss of the largest financial asset most households will ever own.74 This greatly compromises the household’s ability to borrow for important investments like higher education, retirement, or to provide for future generations.75 The lowered credit score resulting from 73 Tad Friend, Cash for Keys, NEW YORKER, Apr. 6, 2009 (describing the dramatic dislocation effects of foreclosure on individual households and the potential for social upheaval as a result of foreclosure crisis); see, e.g., Prentiss Cox, Foreclosure Reform Amid Mortgage Lending Turmoil: A Public Purpose Approach, 45 HOUS. L. REV. 683, 726–27 (2008) (describing the devastating impact to individual households and neighborhoods, especially where foreclosures are concentrated). See generally Florence Wagman Roisman, The Right to Remain: Common Law Protections for Security of Tenure: An Essay in Honor of John Otis Calmore, 86 N.C.L. REV. 817 (2008) (describing the impact of eviction on families and society at large). 74 NEIGHBORHOOD HOUS. SERVICES OF CHICAGO, PRESERVING HOMEOWNERSHIP: COMMUNITY-DEVELOPMENT IMPLICATIONS OF THE NEW MORTGAGE MARKET 21 (Mar. 25, 2004), available at http://www.nw.org/ network/neighborworksProgs/foreclosuresolutionsOLD/documents/preserving HomeownershipRpt.pdf. 75 Lois R. Lupica, The Consumer Debt Crisis and the Reinforcement of Class Position, 40 LOY. U. CHI. L.J. 557, 607 & n.274 (Spring 2009) (“At the point where a consumer’s liabilities eclipse his or her assets, the indicators of upward class mobility—economic equilibrium and stability, the ability to enhance human capital in order to specialize, the wherewithal to take risks and have a positive vision of the future, as well as the capacity to offer future generations greater opportunities—correspondingly CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 81 foreclosure makes future homeownership more difficult, may decrease job prospects, and limits the ability to obtain insurance or rental housing.76 The changes in school, friends and social networks are disruptive to children’s development.77 The accumulation of these decreased opportunities as a result of the loss of one’s home affect an individual’s positive vision of the future and ability to rebound—ultimately resulting in the loss of middle class status.78 2. Foreclosure Effects on Neighborhoods At a community level, foreclosures lead to blight and disinvestment.79 Most immediately, foreclosures of multifamily disappear . . . . Moreover, the loss of a home is the loss of an asset that could have been handed down to the next generation.”). 76 Dan Immergluck & Geoff Smith, The External Costs of Foreclosure: The Impact of Single-Family Mortgage Foreclosures on Property Values, 17 HOUSING POLICY DEBATE 57, 58 (2006); see also, NEIGHBORHOOD HOUS. SERVICES OF CHICAGO, supra note 74, at 13–20. 77 See Christine Vidmar, Seven Ways Foreclosures Impact Communities, NeighborWorks America, Aug. 2008, available at http://neighborworks. issuelab.org/research/listing/seven_ways_foreclosures_impact_communities; see also Phillip Lovell & Julia Issacs, The Impact of the Mortgage Crisis on Children, FIRST FOCUS, May 2008, at 1, available at http://www.firstfocus. net/Download/HousingandChildrenFINAL.pdf. 78 Jeannie Suk, Taking the Home, 20 CARDOZO STUD. LAW & LITERATURE 291, 295 (“The social meaning of home loss is the loss of a family’s economic stability, and with that the loss of middle-class status.”); see also Robert Schiller, The Scars of Losing a Home, N.Y. TIMES, May 18, 2008, at 5 (“[I]t is important to consider the psychological trauma of foreclosure [since homeownership is a] fundamental part of a sense of belonging to a country.”); Brad Heath & Charisse Jones, In Denver, Foreclosures and a Dramatic Exodus, USA TODAY, Apr. 2, 2008, at A1 (“For hundreds of homeowners in this mostly middle-class corner of Denver—and an estimated 1.2 million more nationwide—the wave of foreclosures battering U.S. financial markets is quickly unraveling the American dream. Those who have lost homes here describe seeing their lives crumble into anxiety and embarrassment.”). 79 See Prentiss Cox, Foreclosure Reform Amid Mortgage Lending Turmoil: A Public Purpose Approach, 45 HOUS. L. REV. 683, 686 (2008) (“Rising foreclosures have started to blight certain areas of American cities CHASE REVISED.DOC 82 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY buildings usually result in the displacement of tenants. Secretary Shaun Donovan of the U.S. Department of Housing & Urban Development (HUD) recently stated that 40% of those displaced to date from the foreclosure crisis have been renters.80 The federal government has tried to address the effect of foreclosures on tenants. Congress passed a new law in May 2009 that protects tenants from immediate eviction by persons or entities that become owners of property through foreclosure. Under the law, the immediate successor in interest at foreclosure must: (a) provide bona fide tenants with 90 days notice prior to eviction; and, (b) allow bona fide tenants with leases to occupy property until the end of the lease term, except the lease can be terminated on 90 days notice if the unit is sold to a purchaser who will occupy the property.81 In New Jersey and New Hampshire, with statutes that restrict a landlord’s right to evict for good cause, bona fide renters are protected when their buildings are foreclosed.82 Despite these efforts to limit the effects of foreclosure, communities surrounding foreclosed homes have suffered greatly in the current crisis. Increasingly, foreclosures result in vacancies, which in turn lead to an array of public health concerns. These concerns include arson, which in turn exposes lead paint, trash accumulation, illegal dumping, and rodent infestations.83 In hit hardest by the problem.”). 80 Erika Morphy, HUD Plays Key Role in Financial System Revamp, GLOBE ST., June 18, 2009, available at http://www.globest.com/news/ 1435_1435/washington/179338; see also, Abby Goodnough, Hard Times Hitting New England Three Deckers, New England’s City Backdrop, N.Y.TIMES, June 20, 2009, at A1 (chronicling how multifamily buildings in New England’s cities are being foreclosed on as a higher rate than homes overall); Vicki Been & Allegra Glasshauser, The Worst of Times: Perspectives on and Solutions for the Subprime Mortgage Crisis, 2 ALB. GOV’T L. REV 1, 2–3 (2009) (chronicling how foreclosure crisis is “significantly impacting renters throughout the country” because most states allow the purchaser at a foreclosure sale to evict the existing tenants). 81 See Helping Families Save Their Homes Act of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111–22, 123 Stat. 1632 (2009). 82 See Been & Glasshauser, supra note 80, at 16. 83 John P. Relman, Foreclosures, Integration, and the Future of the Fair CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 83 addition, foreclosures result in higher crime rates for the surrounding community.84 This type of blight decreases property values of neighboring homeowners and thus dissuades further investment.85 Community destabilization and disinvestment are especially pronounced where foreclosures are geographically concentrated.86 3. Foreclosure Effects on Local Governments Finally, foreclosures have a detrimental impact on the fiscal stability of states and localities in which they occur. For example, one study found that foreclosures in Chicago involve Housing Act, 41 IND. L. REV. 629, 650 (2008) (“Foreclosures mean abandoned homes; increased risks of fire, crime, and drugs; increases in homelessness and job loss; deterioration of schools; and a crippling shortage of city funds for existing social programs.”) 84 Dan Immergluck & Geoff Smith, The Impact of Single-Family Mortgage Foreclosures on Neighborhood Crime, 21 HOUSING STUD. 851, 863 (2006) (“These findings suggest that foreclosures may have important social and economic consequences on neighborhoods beyond effects on the finances of households directly affected by the foreclosure. An increase in violent crime is an important social cost, as well as an economic cost, that must be incorporated into policy making concerning real estate and mortgage lending policies and regulation.”); see also, Michael Powell & Janet Roberts, Minorities Affected Most as New York Foreclosures Rise, N.Y. TIMES, May 16, 2009 (citing Immergluck & Smith). 85 See Immergluck & Smith, supra note 84, at 58; Soaring Spillover: Accelerating Foreclosures to Cost Neighbors $502 Billon in 2009 Alone, CENTER FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, May 7, 2009, http://www.responsible lending.org/mortgage-lending/research-analysis/soaring-spillover-acceleratingforeclosures-to-cost-neighbors-436-billion-in-2009-alone-73-4-million-homeslose-5-900-on-average.html; see also Vidmar, supra note 77; Elsa Brenner, Freeing Towns to Tackle Blight, N.Y. TIMES, Apr. 5, 2009, at RE9 (describing effect of foreclosures on local property values in affluent neighborhoods of Mount Vernon, NY). 86 See Jenny Schuetz et al., Neighborhood Effects of Concentrated Mortgage Foreclosures (NYU Center for Law and Economics, Working Paper No. 08–41 2008), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1270121; Cox, supra note 79, at 693. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 84 more than a dozen city agencies and generate costs that in some cases exceeded $30,000 per property.87 Other effects include declining property tax revenues resulting from declining property values described above.88 Thus the foreclosures create a downward spiral effect: just at the time that local governments are called on to deal with the effects of the foreclosure crisis, that very crisis has resulted in less tax revenue with which to help. In sum, the detrimental effects of the housing bubble and crash have extended far beyond the foreclosed homeowners. One category of victims of the foreclosure crisis, renters, have been suffering from decades of government neglect. IV. THE CRISIS IN RENTAL HOUSING The damage wrought by millions of foreclosures has, among other things, exposed the chronic crisis in the rental housing market. There are two fundamental defects in the rental housing market: (i) there is a desperate lack of rental housing affordable to low- and moderate- income households; and (ii) there is a need for increasing the options through which renters can obtain economic and psychological stability in their housing. Each will be explored in turn. A. Need for More Affordable Rental Housing As noted in the introductory section, almost one third of all 89 Americans (36 million households) are renters. Furthermore, 87 WILLIAM C. APGAR & MARK DUDA, WASH. DC: HOMEOWNERSHIP PRESERVATION FOUND., COLLATERAL DAMAGE: THE MUNICIPAL IMPACT OF TODAY’S MORTGAGE FORECLOSURE BOOM 4 (2005), http://www.995hope. org/content/pdf/Apgar_Duda_Study_Short_Version.pdf. 88 Alan Weinstein, Current and Future Challenges to Local Governments Posed by the Housing and Credit Crisis, 2 ALB. GOV’T L. REV. 259, 266 (2008) (describing challenges including revenue shortfalls and rising costs); see also Vidmar, supra note 77 at 2–3. 89 See Donald R. Haurin et al., The Impact of Neighborhood Homeownership Rates: A Review of the Theoretical and Empirical Literature, CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 85 the number of households needing rental housing is expanding. A recent report found that: “the number of renter households jumped by 2.8 percent or nearly one million in 2007.”90 And that trend had already begun before the worst of the foreclosure wave hit—the foreclosure crisis has added many families to the list of those who are in need of rental housing.91 All renters must deal with the fact that the supply of rental units has not been keeping up with demand.92 One study found that “84% of all the new housing units built from 1990 to 2006 were single family units . . . although an average of 34% of all households were renters during that entire period.”93 A vast majority of these single family units built were for sale and not offered as rentals.94 The failure of the rental supply to meet the growing demand has exacerbated the affordability gap that has long plagued many rental households. Indeed, by the end of 2007 almost half of all rental households in the United States were rent burdened95 (spending more than 30% of their gross income on housing J. HOUSING RESEARCH 119–51 (2003); see also Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 3; see also Katz & Turner, supra note 5, at 2. 90 See HARVARD UNIV. JOINT CTR. FOR HOUS. STUDIES, AMERICA’S RENTAL HOUSING-THE KEY TO A BALANCED NATIONAL POLICY 2 (2008) [hereinafter HARVARD UNIV. CTR. FOR JOINT HOUSING STUDIES, BALANCED POLICY], available at http://www.jchs.harvard.edu/publications/rental/rh08_ americas_rental_housing/rh08_americas_rental_housing_bw.pdf; see also id. at 8 (“Today’s mortgage makers woes will not only force many owners into the rental market but also limit the homebuyers opportunities for other lowerincome renters.”); id. at 9 (“If foreclosures continue to rise, renter household growth could return to levels not seen in a decade.”). 91 See id. at 8. 92 See, e.g., Benson, supra note 2, at 2 (“For years, growth in the number of renters at all income levels has far outpaced the construction of new rental units.”). 93 See Downs Why, supra note 9, at 7. 94 See id. 95 See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 23. (“The most common standard of housing affordability in the [U.S.] is 30% of income. Households spending 30% or more of their pre-tax income on housing are viewed as having a excessive housing cost burden.”). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 86 costs) and 24% of all rental households were severely rent burdened96 (spending more than 50% of their gross income on housing costs).97 These numbers represented significant increases from just seven years prior, in 2001.98 Looking at such numbers, as well as the increased number of rental units needed to house foreclosed households, Arthur Nelson, director of the University of Utah’s Metropolitan Research Center, recently concluded that half of all the units built in the coming years need to be rentals.99 Whether or not that figure is precise, the larger point is that the United States needs significant investment in rental housing in order to correct the market imbalances and bring rents more in line with families’ incomes. Notably, two corollaries of the current housing crisis—the glut of vacant homes and increased number of homes converted from for sale to rental status—seem to be reducing market rents charged.100 In Phoenix investors are reportedly purchasing 96 See id. (“Housing cost burdens are defined as severe when housing expenses amount to 50% or more of income.”). 97 HARVARD UNIV. JOINT CTR. FOR HOUS. STUDIES, THE STATE OF THE NATION’S HOUSING 2009 3 tbl.A–5 (2009), available at http://www.jchs. harvard.edu/publications/markets/son2009/son2009.pdf [hereinafter JOINT CTR. FOR HOUS. STUDIES, State of the Nation]; see Katz & Turner, supra note 5, at 38 (“[G]ross rents . . . have grown faster than inflation while median renter’s monthly income has declined 7.3 percent since 2000.”); NAT’L LOW INCOME HOUS. COAL., OUT OF REACH 4 (2009) available at http://www.nlihc.org/oor/oor2009/oor2009pub.pdf (calculating the current “housing wage,” or the amount it takes to afford a modest two-bedroom apartment at 30 percent of income, with the 2009 the national average housing wage is $17.84 per hour, which was more than $3 in excess of the average national hourly wage and more than $10 in excess of the national minimum wage). 98 See HARVARD UNIV. CTR. FOR JOINT HOUSING STUDIES, STATE OF THE NATION, supra note 97, at 38 tbl.A–5 (11.2% increase in households rent burdened and 19.2% increase in those severely rent burdened). 99 See El Nasser, supra note 72 (noting that edges of metropolitan areas will turn into “exurban ghettos” as many units are turned over to renters). 100 See Nick Timiraos, Apartment Glut Expands, WALL ST. J., Oct. 6, 2009 (citing a report showing 7.9% vacancy rate for apartments and a 2.7% decrease in effective rental prices nationally); Shahien Nasiripour, Unable to Sell Their Houses, Millions of Homeowners are Turning Into Landlords, CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 87 foreclosed homes from banks at drastically reduced prices and then renting them to the same households that have been foreclosed.101 Along with others,102 Dean Baker of the Center for Economic Policy Research has proposed that mortgage servicers be forced to rent to delinquent homeowners at market rental prices as a part of a negotiated foreclosure.103 Reportedly, officials from the Obama Administration are considering Baker’s proposal.104 While future substantial drops in rental prices may occur, the real estate crisis thus far has resulted in only a relatively small reduction in rental prices.105 There is no evidence that the housing market has in any long lasting way addressed the affordability crisis that has built up since the 1980s.106 HUFFINGTON POST, Sept. 14, 2009, http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2009/09/ 14/unable-to-sell-their-hous_n_283655.html (describing 2.5 million units being converted from for sale to rentals since 2007, although many may be rentals only until the for sale market picks up). 101 See David Streitfeld, Amid Housing Bust, Phoenix Begins a New Frenzy, N.Y. TIMES, May 24, 2009, at A1. 102 See, e.g., David Kappell, A Rental Model Could Solve The Housing Crisis, NEWSDAY, Apr. 17, 2009, available at http://www.newsday.com/ opinion/a-rental-model-could-solve-the-housing-crisis-1.1219384. The author, a former mayor on Long Island, notes the fact that millions of homes lie dormant waiting for buyers while millions of households need housing as a result of foreclosure, proposing that mortgage servicers agree to rent homes in foreclosure to the current occupants. 103 See DEAN BAKER, THE RIGHT TO RENT PLAN (Ctr. for Econ. Policy Research 2009), available at http://www.cepr.net/documents/publications/ right-to-rent-2009-07.pdf. 104 See Patrick Rucker, Obama Mulls Rental Option for Homeowners, REUTERS, July 14, 2009, http://www.reuters.com/article/euRegulatoryNews/ idUSN1429055220090714. 105 See Timiraos, supra note 100 (citing a 2.7% decrease in effective rental prices nationally); JOINT CTR. FOR HOUS. STUDIES, State of the Nation, supra note 97 at 21 (real rents fell by 0.2 percent nationally in 2008). 106 See JOINT CTR. FOR HOUS. STUDIES, Balanced Policy, supra note 90, at 3 (“With these large, unprecedented shifts on both the demand and supply sides of the rental market, the direction of rents is impossible to predict.”); see also Joint Center for Housing Studies, Fact Sheet-America’s Rental Housing-The Key to a Balanced National Policy, Apr. 30, 2008 (noting new CHASE REVISED.DOC 88 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY As detailed below, changes to U.S. government housing policy107 over the past thirty years have resulted in fewer rental units being built and maintained that are affordable to low and moderate income households. The first of these changes has been the dramatic decrease in federal funding appropriated through HUD for rental subsidies.108 (As discussed in Section I.B, this has been accompanied by a dramatic increase in federal subsidies going to homeowners). Specifically, HUD has funded virtually no new public housing units since 1980 and drastically cut back on the number of projects receiving building wide Section 8 assistance.109 Not only has new production of HUDassisted units diminished, but also hundreds of thousands of previously HUD-assisted units have been removed by their owners from the applicable governmental programs and brought to market rate.110 In addition, changes to the Income Tax Law in wave of foreclosed homes being rented but stating that “most renters do not have adequate income to take advantage of these opportunities”); National Low Income Housing Coalition, New Census Housing Data Confirm Number of Renters Facing Housing Problems on the Rise, Sept. 23, 2009 (analyzing national census data and finding that, from 2006 to 2008, median gross rents increased from $763 to $824 and that the number of rent burdened households increased by 600,000). 107 While I focus here on national housing policy, local governments have also played a role in restricting the number of rental units. Many of the suburban and exurban communities which have grown so quickly over the past thirty years have increasingly restricted zoning to exclude larger multifamily buildings, or even rentals at all. This drives up the price of land in communities which do allow for rentals and thereby decreases the supply and affordability of housing that can be built. See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 37. 108 See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 40–42. 109 See id. at 42. Project based Section 8 was a HUD administered program during the 1980’s which gave owners rent subsidies for all qualified units. 110 See id. at 36; see also Benson, supra note 2, at 2 (“Beyond cutting back the level of spending on public housing operations and maintenance, the Bush administration set policies at HUD that effectively reduced the number of rental vouchers in use. Meanwhile, demolitions under HOPE VI, signed into law by President George Bush in 1992, have driven a net loss of about 165,000 public housing units since 1995.”). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 89 1986 eliminated most of the accelerated depreciation benefits that had until then been provided to investors in all rental housing projects, with even more generous benefits for investors of low income rental housing.111 While the introduction of the low income housing tax credit (LIHTC)112 has had some success in replacing accelerated depreciation as an incentive for equity investment in low income rental projects, LIHTC funded projects have not been able to stem the overall loss of affordable units.113 Overall, the federal government spends roughly $30 billion annually to support rental housing for low to moderate income households.114 This is less than one fourth of what it spends for homeownership programs.115 This disparity, together 111 See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 63, 78–81. In addition to the challenge to the equity side of the financing model presented by the Tax Reform Act of 1986, debt financing for multifamily rental housing was severely curtailed by the failure of so many thrifts on the 1980’s which had been the primary lenders for such rental projects. See id. at 62. The legislative response to the failure of thrifts (the S+L Crisis) exacerbated this development, creating significantly more restrictions on lending to multifamily buildings as compared with single family properties. See id. at 62–63. 112 See I.R.C. § 42 (LEXIS 1986). 113 See SCHWARTZ supra note 9, at 81. 114 See Gale et al., supra note 16, at 1172–73 (citing $30 billion number for 2005, which includes grant funds administered through HUD and the Department of Agriculture for farmer/rural housing as well as various tax benefits administered by the Treasury Department which support the investment in low income rental housing, note that some of the funding in this category goes to support homeownership programs as well so getting the exact amount spent on rental programs is difficult); see also SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 69 (citing $30 billion in “direct” housing subsidies, as opposed to tax expenditures, some small percentage of this includes homeownership subsidies); Downs, Why, supra note 9, at 7 (reporting that the total federal outlays on rental housing were approximately $32.3 billion for 2005. The highest percentage of this category of federal spending is forgone tax revenue supporting the LIHTC program, as well as federal outlays made to fund Section 8 vouchers). Section 8 vouchers provide a direct rental subsidy to households, enabling them to spend no more than 30% of their gross income on rent. Id. 115 See Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 12. (“For example, in fiscal year 2001, program outlays for the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban CHASE REVISED.DOC 90 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY with federal funding decisions begun after World War II which have prioritized highways over mass transit and similar antiurban and anti-density measures, have distorted the market for rental housing by favoring construction and ownership of single family suburban and exurban homes.116 Beyond the need for more rental units generally, and affordable units in particular, there is a further need for more stable rental options for a growing number of households. B. Need for Rental Stability A report completed before the foreclosure crisis found that the number of stable renters was already significant: “More than a quarter of renter households surveyed in 2005 reported they had lived in their units for five or more years.”117 With more opportunities for stable tenure and some rent protection as proposed below, that number would undoubtedly be significantly higher. The category of households seeking stable tenancies includes, at a minimum, low- to moderate-income families who are looking to put down roots in a community, senior citizens Development totaled $33.6 billion. In contrast, that same fiscal year federal tax expenditures for housing totaled $121.2 billion with tax related expenditures for homeowners (including mortgage interest and property tax deductions, and capital gains exclusion) accounting for $106 billion of that total.”); see also Section II.B and sources cited therein. 116 See Thomas J. Sugrue, The New American Dream: Renting, WALL ST. J., Aug. 15, 2009 (“Federal housing policies changed the whole landscape of America, creating the sprawlscapes that we now call home and in the process, gutting inner cities . . . .”). See generally JACKSON, supra note 14. 117 HARVARD UNIV. JOINT CTR. FOR HOUSing. STUDIES, THE STATE OF THE NATION’S HOUSING 2008, supra note 52, at 23. Cf. Ellickson, The Mediocrity, supra note 52, at 15 (stating that each year “about one-third of U.S. tenant households move to new quarters” according to a 2003 study from the U.S. Department of Commerce); Ellickson, Legal Constraints, supra note 52, at 6 n. 8 (citing an annual moving rate in the United States of 32.5% for renters and 9.1% for owners, compared with annual moving rates of 17% for French renters and 4% for French homeowners). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 91 and the disabled.118 In addition, the millions of foreclosures will dramatically increase the number of tenants who need augmented rental stability.119 To the extent that some of these households can create sustainable homeownership solutions, such a result would be a good outcome for those households. But there is undoubtedly some significant percentage of the American population for which homeownership does not make sense.120 Under our free market based economic and property systems, many households do not have the financial means and/or the desire to be homeowners, with the full set of responsibilities that homeownership entails.121 118 See Courtney Gross, Affordable Housing Not Included, Gotham Gazette, Oct. 5, 2009 (describing disabled woman whose rent in the gentrified neighborhood of Williamsburg, Brooklyn was recently raised from $550 to $2100 when her building was purchased by a new owner). 119 See supra notes 74–76 and accompanying text. 120 See Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 5 (“Public policy should focus on the larger goals of promoting access to decent and affordable housing, along with expanding social and economic opportunity for all, and in doing so recognize that promoting homeownership is just one of many possible means for achieving these end goals.”). But see Dalton Connolly, Op Ed., Safe at Home, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 4, 2009 (arguing in favor of increased programs to promote and protect homeownership options for low-income households). 121 See Godsil & Simunovich, supra note 9, at 969–70 for a discussion of the rights and responsibilities of homeowners and renters (“[He or she] who owns a fee simple possesses the largest possible share of the rights in the iconic property bundle (use, possession, the right to exclude, and the right to transfer), while a person or family who possesses a leasehold interest has occupancy rights to the property only for a specified period of time . . . . [T]he fee owner of a rental property is also subject to legally imposed obligations to the leaseholder, like ensuring that the property is habitable.”); see also Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 10 (“[T]enant/landlord laws and regulations govern the obligation of the property owner to meet certain standards of service provision and process concerning rent setting and eviction, as well as responsibilities of the tenant (including making rent payments in a timely manner). At the same time, tenants retain the option to vacate the property on relatively short notice . . . . Home owners generally have a more expansive set of rights, but also more responsibilities. Local zoning, building and health codes along with other land use regulations impose responsibilities on owners . . . or otherwise place limitations on the use of an owner occupied property.”). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 92 As demonstrated above, the demand for moderately priced rental units exceeds supply in many parts of the United States. This gives landlords enormous leverage over low to moderateincome rental households, and puts such tenants at a severe disadvantage when trying to bargain for long-term rental security. Thus many tenants are vulnerable to eviction on thirty days notice at the end of their leases.122 Indeed, a study completed in 1999 found that more than 97% of all private market residential leases (outside jurisdictions with rent regulation123) are for 1 year or less.124 Given the failure of the market to provide sufficient affordable and stable rental units, it is understandable that many families overstretched their budgets in the past 15 years to purchase a home.125 One recent study demonstrated the relationship between the lack of affordable and stable rental options and the demand for homeownership by proving that households use homeownership to insure or “hedge” against predicted increases in future rent payments.126 The authors 122 See Chester Hartman & David Robinson, Evictions: The Hidden Housing Problem, 14 HOUSING POL’Y DEBATE 461, 463 (“[F]ew lowerincome tenants have leases, and if there is no lease . . . a landlord can evict without stating a reason, with only 30 days’ notice.”); Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 56 (“[M]any families with children presumably would also value a chance to remain in their rental apartment for some time, but lacking a steady and secure source of income struggle to do so.”). 123 In this paper I use the term “rent regulation” to refer generally to local and state laws which restrict the ability of landlords to raise rents. Thus rent regulation includes rent control, rent stabilization, rent restrictions and the like. 124 See David Genesove, The Nominal Rigidity of Apartment Rents 16, tbl.7 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 7137, 1999), available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w7137 (using data obtained from the Property Owners and Managers Survey). 125 See Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 5 (“[M]any low-wealth and lowincome families are being ‘pushed’ into homeownership, not necessarily because they fully appreciate the implications of their choices, but because they perceive (or rather hope) that homeownership in and of itself will help them achieve a better life.”). 126 Todd Sinai & Nichola S. Souleles, Owner-Occupied Housing as a Hedge Against Rent Risk, 120 Q. J. ECON., 763 (2005); see also Fennell, CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 93 summarized their findings by saying that “the rent-hedging benefit substantially increases the demand for owner occupied housing, for the population as a whole and especially for the elderly.”127 This study, together with the inadequacy of the rental options available to households at the lower end of the socioeconomic scale, suggest that improving the availability of affordable and stable rental options would reduce the demand for homeownership among such households. While such reduced demand is inconsistent with housing policy of the past 20 years, it is exactly the right response to the current foreclosure crisis.128 V. RENTAL STABILITY PROGRAM PROPOSED Now is the time for policy makers to implement new protections for rental households. The growing crisis for families seeking affordable and stable rental options makes this a crucial imperative. The harder question to answer is what kind of rental protections are needed and what effect such protections will have on the overall market for rental housing. In drafting my proposal, my fundamental goal is to create increased opportunities for renters to obtain some meaningful measure of security in their tenure. Achieving stability of an infinite 129 (the present duration, as promised by homeownership supra note 8, at 1054–55 (“A much-cited advantage of owning a home is the element of price protection it provides. In housing markets without rent control, tenants face significant uncertainty about how much their current housing will cost in future periods.”). 127 Sinai & Souleles, supra note 126. 128 See JOINT CTR. FOR HOUS. STUDIES 2009 at 25 (advocating for “new recognition of the risks that homeownership brings” and suggesting that now is a good time “to rethink federal affordable housing policy, which has until recently strongly favored homeownership programs”). Cf. Joseph Williams, President Shifts Focus to Renting, Not Owning, BOSTON GLOBE, Aug. 16, 2009 (quoting Massachusetts Representative Barney Frank as stating that “the American dream should be a home—not homeownership”). 129 See Fennell, supra note 8, at 1056 (“In contrast [to renters], all homeowners possess something very valuable—the option to remain in their current homes for as long as they wish, provided they make the necessary mortgage and tax payments.”). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 94 foreclosure crisis notwithstanding) is not my goal. Rather, tenants should have the option to enter into leases for a minimum of 5 years, and have rights to renew leases at reasonable rental increases for some certain amount of time, I propose ten years, absent certain changed or exigent circumstances on the landlord’s side.130 A. Rental Stability Program Detailed The Rental Stability Program (hereinafter “the RSP”) I propose for states and localities to consider131 has a basic structure akin to the rent stabilization regime currently in effect in New York City,132 with some important differences that seek to accomplish my goals of increasing rental stability without undermining the basic market incentives for landlords. Under the RSP, landlords of buildings with more than 5 rental units would be required to register their rental units with an administrative body at an initial rent set only by the market. Landlords would be required to offer tenants the option to lease for terms of at least 1, 2 or 5 years.133 No matter which term of 130 See Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 56 (“To help families maintain longer term occupancy, and make better use of available support services, it would be useful to create model landlord tenant laws that include clearly articulated and easily enforceable residential leases designed to promote longer-term, more stable occupancy.”). 131 As detailed infra in Section V, my proposal would require enabling legislation at the state level, and then be subject to adoption (or not) by municipal governments. Since RSP is designed to be appropriate in a number of urban housing markets, some of its parameters are subject to change as dictated by choices by state and local governments. 132 For an introduction to New York City’s rent stabilization regimes, see TIMOTHY COLLINS, AN INTRODUCTION TO THE NEW YORK CITY RENT GUIDELINES BOARD AND THE RENT STABILIZATION SYSTEM (New York City Rent Guidelines Bd. ed., 2006) (2001), available at http://www.housingnyc. com/html/about/intro/toc.html. 133 With this requirement, I seek to adapt a small portion of the European model of residential leases to the American context. France requires a minimum lease term of 3 years for apartments owned by individuals, and 6 years for units owned by corporations, after which time the owner may CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 95 lease is chosen by the tenant, each year rent increases134 would be allowed up to the maximum permitted by a rent guidelines board (hereinafter “RGB”), as is currently in place in New York City.135 The RGB would consider all of the landlords’ legitimate costs in operating buildings (taxes and other fees, maintenance, utilities, labor, cost of capital) and calculate reasonable increases for the coming year.136 Additional increases would be allowed based on needed repairs completed to the individual unit or the building. In addition to the rent increases to cover the landlords’ costs, the landlord would be permitted market-based increases at the earliest of the following points in time: (i) ten years after the initial lease date of that tenant; (ii) the commencement of the fourth consecutive lease renewal by the same tenant; and (iii) vacancy of the unit. At the end of the term of the lease, absent certain good cause factors, the landlord would be required to offer tenants a renewal lease with the same term options (1, 2 or 5 years). New tenants would have the exact same deal, that is, the initial rent would be set at market and the terminate the lease or get market rent increases. See Jane Ball, Renting Homes: Status and Security in the UK and France: A Comparison In the Light Of the Law Commission’s Proposals, 67 CONV. & PROP. LAW. 50 (2003); see also Andrea Carroll, The International Trend Toward Requiring Good Cause for Tenant Eviction: Dangerous Portents for the United States, 38 SETON HALL L. REV. 427, 440, 446 n.139 (2008) (discussing the reasons a French landlord can terminate a lease and describing a 1978 Landlord Tenant law which dictates that Italian leases cannot be less than 4 years). 134 The rationale for annual rent increases is based largely on my interview with Marvin Markus, who explained that projecting costs more than one year in advance in purely speculative. It was this rationale, Markus stated, that led to a change in 1983 which limited the choice of New York City Rent Stabilized tenants to one or two years; prior to the enactment of the Omnibus Housing Act of 1983, tenants were given the additional option of choosing three year leases. Interview with Marvin Markus, Chairman, Rent Guidelines Bd. held at Markus’ offices at Goldman Sachs on June 1, 2009; see COLLINS, supra note 132, at 35 (stating legal change but not asserting rationale). 135 For an introduction to the RGB in New York City, see generally COLLINS, supra note 132. 136 For a list of factors the New York RGB considers, on which my proposal is based, see N.Y. Unconsol. Law § 26-510 (McKinney 2009). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 96 tenant would have the option of a 1, 2 or 5 year lease, with annual increases set by the RGB. To protect the settled economic expectations of certain classes of tenants who desire long-term stability, an integral part of the RSP is a new rental subsidy modeled loosely on New York’s existing Senior Citizen Rent Increase Exemption.137 Tenants under a specific income threshold, which I suggest be set at somewhere between 80-120% of the area median income,138 would be entitled to a federally funded rental subsidy139 to cover all rent increases from the initial registered rent (which include the allowable increase for that year as set by the RGB, as well as increases permissible for that specific building or unit due to improvements). In addition to the income 137 See N.Y. Unconsol. Laws. Law § 26-509 (Mckinney 2009); see also ANDREW SCHERER & FERN FISHER, RESIDENTIAL LANDLORD-TENANT LAW IN NEW YORK §4:305 (2008) (summary of SCRIE law). 138 I suggest that the RSP rental subsidy be provided to households with incomes at or below 80–120% of Area Median Income (AMI) for the following reasons: First, for the 80% ceiling, HUD defines low income as households at or below 80% of AMI and any low income household should be included in the rental subsidy. A higher threshold of eligibility for the RSP rental subsidy may be appropriate for areas which have exceptionally high housing costs—for example, the City of New York Housing Development Corporation has programs targeting households with incomes at or below 130% of AMI, recognizing that in such an expensive city, higher income households still need assistance with housing expenses. See New York City Hous. Dev. Corp., New Housing Opportunities Program—New HOP, http://www.nychdc.com/pdf/developers/new.hop.termsheet_2008.pdf (last visited Sept. 30, 2009) (term sheet for the 2008 “New HOP” program). As background, the website for Freddie Mac defines “Area Median Income” as follows: “Midpoint in the family-income range for a metropolitan statistical area or for the non-metro parts of a state. The figure often is used as a basis to stratify incomes into low, moderate and upper ranges.” Cf. Adams, Homeownership, supra note 60, at 577 (quoting Census Department definition of Median income: “the amount which divides the income distribution into two equal groups, half having incomes above the median, half having incomes below the median”). 139 Cf. BRUCE KATZ & MARGERY AUSTIN TURNER, RETHINKING U.S. RENTAL HOUSING POLICY 8–9 (Harvard University Joint Center for Housing Studies 2007) (suggesting new pools of housing vouchers, akin to Section 8, to address rental needs in high cost areas). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 97 threshold, receipt of the RSP rental subsidy would be available only to households who do not already receive Section 8 or other rental subsidies, and who affirm in a sworn statement that (i) the rent exceeded 30% of the household’s gross income for the year prior to lease renewal as reported on tax returns,140 and (ii) they expected that the household’s income would remain below the threshold income level for the coming year. Subsidies for the future years of the lease term would be subject to the tenant providing similar proof and affirmation to the RSP administrative entity. When the landlord takes a market based increase as allowed under the RSP (at the earlier of the fourth consecutive lease renewal or the tenth year from the date of the initial lease), then the rental subsidy would end. It may seem counterintuitive for the RSP rental subsidy to terminate at the point at which market based increases could be taken, since this is the very point at which households would be most vulnerable.141 However, ending the rental subsidy at this point is consistent with the RSP’s overall structure as a modest, time limited program which is designed to keep costs at a minimum.142 The opposite policy of allowing the rental subsidy to continue indefinitely would require the government to subsidize potentially unlimited rent increases. This would lead to budgetary challenges as well as a possible erosion of public support. B. The Fine Print: Legal/Administrative Structure of RSP The RSP is shaped to adapt to many of the urban rental 140 Households spending more than 30% of gross income on housing expenses are considered “rent burdened.” See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 23. 141 I would suggest that the RSP be accompanied with programs similar to those in effect in New York City protecting the elderly and disabled after RSP protections and subsidies expire. See generally COLLINS, supra note 127 (describing the New York City Rent Guidelines Board and Rent Stabilization System). 142 See infra Section V.C. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 98 housing markets throughout the United States.143 There are important differences in these rental markets which impact not only whether a regime like the RSP is good policy, but also the exact contours the program should take.144 These decisions are best left to state and local legislatures. Some of the pertinent differences include the density of the locality,145 the kind and size of rental projects that exist in each community,146 and, with 143 Even among some rent regulation defenders, there is some debate as to whether it should apply outside of New York City. Interview with Marvin Markus., Chairman, Rent Guidelines Bd., held at Markus’ offices at Goldman Sachs on June 1, 2009). They point to New York City being unique in terms of the importance and expense of rental housing to that City. Ellen & O’Flaherty, supra note 52, at 19–36, offer an interesting discussion on this question. They review the statistics comparing New York City to the nation’s nine other biggest cities as well as the nine other most dense cities in terms of percentage of persons who rent, the cost of housing, the length of the rentals, and the density. On the percentage of renters, with 70% New York City is at the top of the biggest cities, but is roughly equal to many smaller cities such as Patterson, Jersey City, San Francisco and Cambridge. Similarly, while New York City is near the top of the list in terms of cost of housing, it is not the highest and when compared with income, is more in the middle of the pack. The only 2 categories analyzed in which New York City is an outlier is the level of density, and the length that New York City households remain in their apartments. Thirty Five percent of New York City renters remained in their apartments between 1990 and 2000, while the comparable number for the U.S. as a whole was under ten percent. Notably, none of the other 9 biggest cities exceeded 18%, and none of the other 9 densest cities exceeded 23%. See id. at 32 & 51 tbl.711. 144 There are a number of specific components of the rent stabilization portion of RSP that need fleshing out, for example whether to allow succession rights to units for cohabitating family members. As indicated infra, the time limited nature of the rent regulation makes these questions less crucial than under unlimited systems. 145 See Ellen & O’Flaherty, supra note 52, at 31 (noting that localities might be more likely to try to promote residential stability in dense “residential environments [where the] development of trust and social capital among neighbors seems more critical”). 146 See JOINT CTR. FOR HOUS. STUDIES, State of the Nation, supra note 97, at 22 & tbl.W-7 (noting that less than 10% of rentals are in buildings with at least fifty units, more than a third of rental units are single-family homes, including condominiums, and more than half are in buildings with fewer than five apartments; also stating that “[s]ize is important because CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 99 respect to the households seeking rental accommodation, their ideal degree of mobility and economic make-up. For example, jurisdictions that have a very high percentage of owners and in which most renters are transitory or temporary may not want or need the RSP. On the other hand, these very communities many have pent up demand for rental units, which would emerge if more stable rental options were offered. Recall the study which found that more than 97% of all residential leases in nonregulated markets are for one year or less.147 Since states and localities would both be involved in implementing the RSP, legislative action at each level would be appropriate. I suggest state legislatures pass authorizing legislation that would enable, but not compel, localities to adopt the RSP within certain state prescribed programmatic parameters.148 Local governments would then choose whether or not to adopt the RSP and if so, exercise discretion to choose the best program within the state prescribed parameters. In addition, I suggest that one state agency be designated as the regulatory authority for each of the localities in the state that adopt the RSP.149 This would ensure consistent statewide application and enforcement of the RSP. That state agency could also supervise the RGB that sets annual cost based increases.150 In addition, the use of federal funds for the RSP rent subsidy requires a programmatic vehicle for distributing these funds. I [different sized] rental buildings differ systematically in location, year of construction, and types of households they attract”). 147 Genesove, The Nominal Rigidity of Apartment Rents, supra note 124. 148 See, e.g., N.Y. Unconsol. Law § 8605 (McKinney’s 2009) (better known as the Urstadt Law, which prevents the City of New York from enacting rent regulation in a manner more restrictive than that authorized by the New York State Legislature). 149 In New York State, the Division of Housing & Community Renewal is charged with this role. See N.Y. COMP. CODES R. & REGS. tit. 9, § 2520.1 (2009) (recognizing powers granted under Chapter 888 of the Laws of New York of 1985). 150 As opposed to the practice in the State of New York, in which each locality with rent regulation has its own rent setting board, I would suggest one statewide RGB, with members appointed by the Governor, the tenant community and the landlord community. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 100 would suggest that the RSP rental subsidy funds be distributed by HUD as a block grant to each state.151 The amount provided to each state would be determined by the number of rental households in the state, a statistic gathered by the U.S. Census Bureau. States that choose not to implement the RSP could use the money for additional Section 8 Voucher Certificates, which are distributed to very low income households to assist in making rent payments.152 C. RSP Evaluation & Discussion: Primary & Secondary Goals 1. Primary Goal As stated above, the fundamental goal of the RSP is to enable renting households to obtain more housing stability. How will the results of the RSP match this goal? First, all renters would have the option of longer lease terms, up to five years, with rights to renew absent good cause for eviction by the owner. Second, all renters would be protected from market based rent increases (and low to moderate income households who are rent-burdened would be protected from all rent increases) for the shorter of ten years and the initiation of the fourth consecutive lease renewal. Taken together, these first two results meet my primary goal of providing more stable options for renting households. While the ten year limitation to the RSP’s rent benefits would undoubtedly be a material hardship for some households, there are compelling reasons to design the RSP in this way. First, ten years of rent protection and rent subsidy (for eligible households) provides families and individuals with sufficient 151 HUD administers a number of block grant programs which provide grants to the states for certain prescribed uses, within which the states have discretion to choose individual projects. The original program was the Community Development Block Grant Program, enacted by Congress in 1974. See 24 C.F.R. 570.1 (2009). 152 For a brief description of the Section 8 Voucher Program, see supra note 110. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 101 time to settle in a community, attach roots, and begin to climb the economic ladder so that market-based rentals would not be out of reach.153 If a family moved into the RSP protected apartment when a child was eight, in third grade, the family’s housing would be protected until the child became 18 and scheduled to graduate from high school. Furthermore, most renting households, whether in jurisdictions with rent regulation or not, end up moving within ten years.154 The reform of the federal welfare programs in the 1990’s provides an apt analogy. These changes included eliminating a guarantee of eligibility for the main cash welfare program (Aid to Families With Dependent Children) as well as the addition or enhancement of other benefits, including job training, child care and other resources designed to enable recipient to gain increased economic independence.155 By some accounts, these reforms helped push 153 Cf. Robert I. Lerman & Signe-Mary McKernan, Promoting Neighborhood Improvement while Protecting Low-Income Families, 8 URB. INST., OPPORTUNITY AND OWNERSHIP PROJECT 2 (2007), available at http://www.urban.org/publications/311457.html (proposing 10 years as length of guarantee for tenants of expected future benefits from renter insurance product, discussed further infra Section VI.A). A valuable addition to RSP, one wise commentator suggested to this author, would be a forced savings program to run contiguously during the ten year period of rental regulation and rental subsidy. This would help ensure that households were indeed more able to afford market rents. Cf. Gale, supra note 16, at 1180–81 (proposing savings program to encourage low and moderate-income households to save for down payments as a part of a complete overhaul of the federal mortgage interest deduction). While devising such a program is beyond the scope of this paper, I note that the Obama Administration proposed a similar concept as part of the 2010 Federal Budget as an alternative to the 401(k) employee savings plans. See Pat Regnier, Why it’s Time to Create an Auto-IRA, CNNMONEY.COM, Feb. 27, 2009, http://moneyfeatures.blogs.money.cnn. com/2009/02/27/why-its-time-to-create-an-auto-ira/. 154 See Ellickson, Legal Constraints, supra note 52, at 8 (“Over a ten year period, 83 percent of Chicago’s renting households changed dwellings, compared to 65 percent of New York [City]’s.”); see also William M. Rohe et al., The Social Benefits and Costs of Homeownership, JOINT CENTER FOR HOUSING STUDIES OF HARVARD UNIVERSITY 13 (2001) (renters maintain their residences for a median duration of 2.1 years). 155 See Ron Haskins, What Works is Work: Welfare Reform and Poverty CHASE REVISED.DOC 102 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY millions of Americans into the work force; they also took away much of the force of the conservative critiques of the existing federal welfare program.156 Similarly, limiting the RSP rent regulation and rental subsidy to ten years would likely push households to increase economic self-sufficiency, thereby helping to assuage potential conservative critics of the RSP.157 More generally, the ten year limitation fits within the RSP’s overall structure as a modest program designed to have an acceptably limited impact on the budget constrained federal government as well as the applicable rental markets.158 The RSP is thus designed to work within the existing governmental and market parameters. The ten-year limitation thus increases the likelihood that an RSP type program will be adopted. The interest in rental housing demonstrated by the Obama Administration provides hope that the RSP will receive a sympathetic consideration in Washington.159 The RSP’s ten-year limit on rent protection reveals another important point about what the RSP aims to achieve and what it doesn’t. The RSP is not aimed at creating affordable housing and should not be judged on such grounds. Why not? Because, the RSP, and rent regulation generally, are not the proper tools for creating or maintaining affordable housing for the long term. While this is contrary to the arguments of some tenant advocates and scholars,160 rent regulation regimes (including the RSP) are Reduction, 4 NW. J. L. & SOC. POL’Y 30 (2009). 156 See id. at 46. 157 The ten year limitation would help assuage the conservative critiques of government funded subsidy programs which are of an infinite duration. See, e.g., the critiques coming from Ronald Utt of the Heritage Foundation, objecting to Public Housing and Section 8 benefits as creating “a culture of dependency that doesn’t encourage families to work or to improve their lot in life.” Benson, supra note 2, at 4. 158 The importance of the ten year limitation to RSP’s limited impact on markets is discussed more below. 159 See Joseph Williams, President Shifts Focus to Renting, Not Owning, BOSTON GLOBE, Aug. 16, 2009 (detailing Administration’s plans to use stimulus funds to create more rental housing affordable to low and moderate income households). 160 See Chester Hartman, Evictions: The Hidden Housing Problem, 14 CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 103 too blunt to achieve the narrow tailoring that the most effective affordable housing programs demand.161 For example, empirical studies of New York City’s rent regulation have found that households with higher incomes are more likely to live in rent regulated housing as compared with low income households.162 The fact that wealthy households benefit from rent regulation in addition to, or even more often than, poor households, does not necessarily mean that that rent regulation should be discontinued. Rather, it means that proponents of rent regulation (and the RSP) must be able to identify important goals served by such programs other than income redistribution.163 In this case, the RSP serves the crucial goal of increasing tenant stability.164 The RSP is favorable to usual rent regulation schemes because it has a more limited effect on the overall rental market and because it features a federally funded rental subsidy which is restricted to low to moderate income households. While the RSP is not an affordable housing program, I strongly support increased funding of the Section 8 Voucher Program and other programs which enable low to moderate HOUSING POL’Y DEBATE 461, 463 (2003). 161 See Edgar Olsen, Is Rent Control Good Social Policy?, 67 CHI. KENT L. REV. 931, 938–40 (1991) (detailing studies showing that benefits of rent regulation accumulate differently to different classes of people, and concluding that due to such random effects, rent regulation “has no merit as a redistributive device”). 162 See Ellen & O’Flaherty, supra note 52, at 9; see also Barros, supra note 62, at 288. 163 Ellen & O’Flaherty, supra note 52, at 28 (identifying income redistribution as one of the usual reasons for housing policy). 164 This is the view of Marvin Markus, chair of the Rent Guidelines Board of New York City, who recently stated that New York City’s Rent Stabilization regime is important as a “guarantee of tenure system . . . its basic premise is not affordability. It is to protect the tenant in occupancy from illegal and large-scale gouging.” See Eliot Brown, Rent Board Chief Marvin Markus Pleads for ‘Rationality’, N.Y. OBSERVER, May 18, 2009, available at http://www.observer.com/2009/real-estate/rent-board-chiefmarvin-markus-pleads-rationality; see also Greg Smithsimon, Rent Regulation: The Right Tool for the Right Job, PLANETIZEN, May 14, 2007, http:// planetizen.com/node/24451 (suggesting that rent regulation’s purpose is to provide housing stability not affordable housing). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 104 income households obtain decent housing at rents they can afford.165 Recent budget proposals and public statements by HUD Secretary Donovan indicate that more resources for rental housing are forthcoming.166 Increasing the strength of programs like the Section 8 Voucher Program is the ultimate answer for those households that are forced to move from the RSP-covered housing after the ten years and are unable to afford market rentals in acceptable areas. 2. Secondary Goal Now I move to an evaluation of how the RSP serves my secondary goal, which is avoiding excessive distortions in rental housing markets and thereby maintaining market-based incentives for landlords. The formulation of this goal is partially based on sensible critiques of rent regulation.167 More 165 See generally Ed Koch & Robert Weiner, Renters Across America Need More Help from Congress, DAILY NEWS (New York City), July 5, 2009, available at http://www.nydailynews.com/opinions/2009/07/05/200907-05_renters_across_america_need_more_help_from_congress.html #ixzz0KTdnOBHC&C. 166 See, e.g., Eugene Gilligan, 90-Degree Turn: Stimulus Package Redirects Housing Efforts to Affordable Rentals, MULTI-HOUSING NEWS, Apr. 14, 2009 (describing how $13 billion in stimulus money is going to HUD’s budget, including $2.3 billion in the Tax Credit Assistance Program which will go to fill gaps in budgets for low income rental construction and rehabilitation projects); Sule Aygoren Carranza, Experts Look at Housing Under Obama Administration, GLOBEST.COM, Jan. 26, 2009, at 3, http://www.globest.com/news/1332_1332/insider/176529-1.html (discussing inclusion in stimulus bill of substantial resources to address multifamily rental housing); Secretary Shaun Donovan, 2009–10 Housing and Urban Development Budget (May 7, 2009) (stating that for too long there has been a federal homeownership policy at expense of a federal policy aimed at affordable rentals and detailing an increase in federal money for rental program, including increased Section 8 voucher funding). 167 See, e.g., Richard A. Epstein, Rent Control and the Theory of Efficient Regulation, 54 BROOK. L. REV. 741 (1988). Epstein’s piece was the seminal article which drew 7 response papers, all printed in a volume of the Brooklyn Law Review. See id at 1215–80; see also William Tucker, How Rent Control Drives Out Affordable Housing, Cato Institute Policy Analysis CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 105 specifically, the consequences I seek to avoid or at least minimize with the RSP include the following: (i) disincentivizing the creation and maintenance of rental housing;168 (ii) creating No. 274 (May 21, 1997), available at http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa274.html (stating that cities that do not use rent control policies are “rewarded with a normal competitive housing market in which housing is available at every price level but [t]hose cities that succumb to the disease of rent control are doomed to never-ending, house-to-house warfare over an ever-diminishing supply of unaffordable housing”); Michael H. Schill, Comment on Chester Hartman and David Robinson’s Evictions: The Hidden Housing Problem, Protection or Protraction?, 14 HOUSING POL’Y DEBATE 503, 513 (2003) (to properly address society housing problems, reforms must work with the market system, and not it against it); c.f. Andrea B. Carroll, The International Trend Toward Requiring Good Cause for Tenant Eviction: Dangerous Portents for the United States, 38 SETON HALL L. REV. 427, 446 n.139 (2008) (making the case against adopting good cause requirements for eviction, which are often but not always accompanied by rent regulation). But see Margaret Jane Radin, Residential Rent Control, 15 PHILOSOPHY & PUBLIC AFFAIRS 350, 365 (Autumn 1986) (“A tenancy, no less than a singlefamily house, is the sort of property interest in which a person becomes selfinvested; and after the self-investment has taken place, retention of the interest becomes a priority claim over curtailment of merely fungible interests of others.”). But see Michael J. Mandel, Does Rent Control Hurt Tenants?: A Reply to Epstein, 54 BROOK. L. REV. 1267, 1273–74) (“It seems clear that rent control is not a perverse public policy which hurts everyone. There are winners and there are losers, and it is important to identify who is who. On the landlord side the losers are people who owned rental housing at the time the original rent control law was passed, and the winners are builders of new apartments . . . . On the tenant side, the elderly and long-term stable households benefit from the low levels of their original rent. People just entering the rental market and renters who move frequently tend to pay higher rents . . . or face long housing searches. Often this means that lowincome households do not receive as much protection from rent regulation.”); Alyssa Katz, OUR LOT: HOW REAL ESTATE CAME TO OWN US 189 (2009) (“[I]t’s impossible to make a blanket case for or against rent control . . . the success or failure depends on gathering good information, exercising the political will to calibrate the annoying details of administration and taking leadership to reconcile conflict.”); Gregory S. Alexander et al., A Statement of Progressive Property, 94 CORNELL L. REV. 743, 744 (2009) (property decisions involve “plural values” and cannot be “adequately understood or analyzed through a single metric”). 168 See Epstein, supra note 167, at 763–67 (criticizing rent control CHASE REVISED.DOC 106 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY rules that are difficult for governments to administer or for owners and tenants to understand and comply with;169 (iii) creating opportunities for abuse, or for shadow rental markets to emerge; and (iv) incentivizing landlords and tenants to dispute and litigate.170 regimes for, among other reasons, creating disincentives for housing production and maintenance); see also Tucker, supra note 167, at 162. However, the empirical case regarding the effects of rent regulation on new construction and housing maintenance are disputed. See Ellen & O’Flaherty, supra note 49, at 24 (citing various studies and concluding that “models that forecast the effects of rent control and rental subsidies on the costs of . . . uncontrolled rental housing . . . are extremely complex and do not give unambiguous answers”); J. Gilderbloom & R. Appelbaum, RETHINKING RENTAL HOUSING 57–67 (1988) (citing numerous studies of landlord behavior and rental housing markets and finding a minimal effect of rent regulation on levels of new construction and maintenance of existing housing); Kenneth K. Baar, Would the Abolition of Rent Controls Restore A Free Market, 54 BROOK. L. REV. 1231, 1232–33 (1989) (citing numerous studies from the 1970s and 1980s, including many commissioned by governments, and concluding that the reports that included data “on new apartment construction in rent controlled jurisdictions have been mixed in their conclusions”); Olsen, supra note 163, at 942–43 (“[T]he effect of rent control on the maintenance of the controlled [housing] stock is ambiguous on theoretical grounds . . . [and] the empirical literature contains no compelling evidence.”); Collins, supra note 133, at 22 (finding that “New York [City’s] two great housing booms . . . occurred during periods when strict rent controls were imposed on existing units”); see also Peter D. Salins, Reflections on Rent Control and the Theory of Efficient Regulation, 54 BROOK. L. REV. 775, 779 (1988) (opponents of rent regulation who make this argument [as to inefficiency] have also relied too heavily on theory, and too little on empirical proof); see also id. at 780 (“[N[o one has yet discovered the research design that will succeed in definitively making the deregulation case.”). 169 For an example of a well intentioned scheme that may be administratively difficult see Megan J. Ballard, Legal Protections for Home Dwellers: Caulking the Cracks to Preserve Occupancy, 56 SYRACUSE L. REV. 277, 307 (2006) (suggesting that, when considering an eviction, a decision maker evaluate various prescribed factors to assess the degree to which a subsidized tenant considers a dwelling to be a home and if so indicated, “the burden should shift to the opposing stakeholder to justify the basis for eviction”). 170 See Michael J. Mandel, Does Rent Control Hurt Tenants? A Reply to CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 107 For this secondary goal, avoiding the above-described unintended consequences, the RSP serves its purpose well, albeit not perfectly. Generally, the RSP seeks to combine the best aspects of existing rent regulation systems and rental subsidy programs, with certain additions suggested by the commercial leasing framework, specifically longer lease options with periodic step up rent increases. Specifically, the RSP would avoid unintended consequences by creating a stock of rental units priced at or near market rents. Units would be priced at or near market because under the RSP landlords could take market increases, at a minimum, every ten years, as well as annual increases to cover increased costs in maintaining and improving their buildings. The protection for tenants is from market increases during their tenancy, up to their fourth lease renewal or ten years. By making the rent regulation time limited and subjecting all units in a jurisdiction to its purview, the RSP Epstein, 54 BROOK. L. REV. 1267, 1271 (1989) (“I agree with Epstein that rent control leads to increased litigation between landlords and tenants. In fact, the primary negative effect of rent regulation, from the viewpoint of landlords, seems to be that it enmeshes them in a bureaucracy designed to regulate housing prices, housing quality, and landlord-tenant relations.”). Other critiques of rent control include the following: (i) it leads to the misallocation of space (see Edward L. Glaeser & Erzo F.P. Luttmer, The Misallocation of Housing Under Rent Control (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 6220, October 1997); Richard A. Epstein, Rent Control Revisited: One Reply to Seven Critics, 54 BROOK. L. REV. 1281, 1289-90 (1988); (ii) that it is arbitrary, (iii) difficult to remove once enacted and introduces politics into housing markets; and (iv) that it is a poor toll for redistributing wealth. My response to these potential critiques of RSP is as follows: (i) I agree that households which change in size during the ten year maximum of rent regulation will have incentives to keep the unit and not move to the appropriate sized unit, but given the important goals served by RSP and the time limitation of this incentive, I am not terribly concerned; (ii) RSP, by incorporating an income restricted rental subsidy, attempts to address this arbitrariness; (iii) while it is important to consider the political economy of rent regulation systems, as Epstein reminds us, like (i) above, in light of the important goals furthered by RSP, ultimately this should not stop any jurisdiction from adopting such a regime; (iv) I agree but as described above, RSP is not aimed at wealth distribution but rather household and neighborhood stability. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 108 would eliminate much of the difference in rents charged to existing and new tenants. This is an important and positive change to most existing rent regulation schemes, since it reduces the current incentives for landlords to harass tenants into leaving. The decreased harassment would likely reduce the amount of landlord-tenant litigation, which in turn would reduce the state’s administrative burden. Similarly, the ten-year limit on rent regulation would greatly reduce the benefit of passing the housing unit to a relative, and therefore the battles over succession rights would be reduced. In addition, in another positive change for landlord tenant relations, the RSP’s rent subsidy for income and rent-burdened households would come at the expense of the federal government and not landlords. Finally, as an ancillary benefit, the federal funds for the RSP rental subsidies would take one step towards achieving a more balanced allocation of federal benefits allocated to renters and owners. D. RSP: Addressing Critiques & Concerns The most basic question is why the RSP is needed. If it were true, as Richard Epstein asserted in 1989, that those seeking increased residential stability could simply purchase homes instead of renting,171 then this would be a short paper indeed. However, Epstein made this assertion prior to the foreclosure crisis, and I am not sure that he would repeat the statement today.172 It is evident from my arguments thus far that there are 171 See Epstein, supra note 167, at 1293 (“So long as the market is well functioning, then persons who desire to have long-term attachments to property can buy instead of rent.”). 172 However, Epstein has stated that much of the expense of housing results from unneeded and unconstitutional government interference in the housing market through building codes and zoning restrictions. See Epstein, supra note 9, at 1287. It is possible that Epstein would argue that, free of such constraints, the market would produce housing at all price points. While such an assertion has a certain ideological appeal for Epstein, it would mean that government would allow housing to be of questionable quality and standard. See SCHWARTZ, supra note 9, at 37 (“It is not certain that the CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 109 a certain percentage of households that simply do not have the economic ability to be homeowners, no matter their desire for stability.173 The more nuanced question is why renters who desire increased stability do not negotiate for longer lease terms. There is some disagreement among wise minds on this question. Robert Ellickson asserts that landlords cannot find tenants to take the longer leases,174 while Professors Fennell & Roin posit that landlords are fearful of such arrangements since tenants have significantly less at stake to hold them to the lease terms, specifically just a security deposit, while landlords are compelled to comply by the tenants’ presence and the availability of court protection.175 Neither Ellickson nor Fennell & Roin cite empirical findings to support their respective propositions but I am inclined to join Fennell & Roin on this point, especially with respect to tenants at the lower-end of the economic spectrum. As removal of such [building code] restrictions would make housing affordable to the lowest income households . . . society may not accept the changes in building and community standards that would be necessary if housing costs were to be reduced to such levels.”). The regulation of single room occupancy or “flophouse” hotels in New York City and San Francisco in the 1970s is one example of the tensions governments must weigh between trying to improving housing conditions and eliminating the market altogether. See Supportive Housing Network of NY, What is Supportive Housing? available at http://www.shnny.org/what_is_history.html (“SRO hotels in New York City were particularly vulnerable to conversion or demolition because of a city tax abatement program . . . [which] created incentives for converting SRO units into market-rate apartments, commercial hotels, or offices. Federal urban renewal programs like Title I also led to the condemnation and demolition of the SRO stock, particularly in midtown Manhattan.”). 173 See supra Part IV.B. 174 See Robert C. Ellickson, Rent Control: A Comment on Olsen, 67 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 947, 951 (1991) (“A residential tenant could also stave off the risk of a rent increase by negotiating a long-term lease; in practice, however, residential landlords, not tenants, typically push to lengthen leases.”). 175 See Lee Ann Fennell & Julie Roin, Controlling Residential Stakes 15 (Univ. of Chicago Law Sch., John M. Olin Law & Econ. Working Paper No. 477, 2009), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract _id=1452887 [hereinafter Fennell & Roin, Controlling]. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 110 demonstrated in Section IV, because of the disparities in supply and demand, low-income tenants have little leverage for decent units priced at rents they can afford. Therefore, I suspect that the landlords are dictating the lease terms in such cases. This strongly implies that landlords are reluctant to enter into longerterm leases, since 97% of the leases in non-regulated markets are for less than a year.176 RSP would also face critiques from scholars, like Ellickson who have questioned the need for rent protection to increase rental stability. Ellickson states, “[r]ather than opportunistically exploiting tenants who have put down roots, landlords instead seem to give them price breaks.”177 While it makes sense for landlords to give some price break to long-term tenants who are proven reliable, public policy cannot rely on such whimsical and haphazard protection for a matter as dire as rental stability. Indeed, if we could rely on landlords to maintain reasonable rents for long-term tenants, landlords would not object to current “moderate” rent regulation statutes, which allow for periodic rental increases.178 If Ellickson’s statement were the full story, 176 See Genesove, supra note 124, at 123. It does seem reasonable that some rental households are reluctant to sign long term leases, which require them to pay for the unit without any “out” clause for changed economic or personal circumstances. This assumed reluctance on the part of tenants might be somewhat addressed by having the rental subsidy proposed by RSP for income challenged tenants, as well as having reasonable rights to assign and/or sublease the unit. For RSP, I would incorporate the New York State Real Property Law Section 226-b. This law provides that a residential tenant may not assign his/her lease without the written consent of the owner, unless the lease expressly provides otherwise. It also provides that a tenant has the right to sublet his/her apartment, even if subletting is prohibited in the lease, provided that the tenant complies strictly with the provisions of the statute, which requires detailed notice to owner. N.Y. REAL PROP. LAW § 226-b (2006). 177 See Ellickson, supra note 174, at 951 (“Contrary to their unsavory reputations, residential landlords are not apt to jack up the real rents charged sitting tenants. Olsen cites five studies that indicate that longtime tenants tend to pay lower rents than do more recently arrived tenants who move into comparable housing units.”). 178 See Mandel, supra note 165, at 1269–70 (distinguishing “strict” rent control systems “which do not allow pass-throughs of rising operating costs, CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 111 rent regulation would simply enforce what landlords would be doing anyway. The vehemence of the landlord’s objection to rent regulation disproves this potential objection to the RSP. Landlords subject to rent regulations that currently exempt new units from regulation179 would, at least initially, object to the RSP requirement of having rents on new units regulated. However, this is a crucial feature of the RSP since it would result in substantially one class of tenants and owners, eliminating the two tiered or “shadow markets” phenomenon occurring under rent stabilization that Epstein and others decry.180 More nuanced critics and landlords will focus not on the fact of regulation, but the nature of regulation. Under the RSP all units must be registered and the initial rents will be set by the market. Similarly, at year ten, or when the tenant vacates or initiates his or her fourth lease renewal, the landlord would be able to take a market increase. In between day one and year ten (at the latest), landlords could take increases for increased costs and repairs. While far from the unregulated market preferred by Epstein and the landlord lobby, the RSP does not impose unreasonable controls. [resulting in landlords finding that] it may become unprofitable to maintain or even keep the building, which leads to abandonment” and “moderate” rent control, which “allow[s] regulated rents to rise with inflation and increased operating costs” noting that moderate rent control laws are much more common than strict rent control and not bad policy); see also GILDERBLOOM & APPELBAUM, supra note 168, at 128–132 (distinguishing “strict” rent control which sets price limits without guaranteeing any right of return from moderate rent control, as defined by Mandel, and “strong” rent control, which was in effect in the 1980s in Santa Monica, Berkley and West Hollywood, which allow increases lower than the Consumer Price Index and no vacancy decontrol). 179 Most current regulation programs exempt new construction from regulation. This includes the programs in New York City, as well as all of the California jurisdictions which have rent regulation. See Katz, supra note 5, at 192. 180 See Epstein, Rent Control Revisited, supra note 170, at 1287 (“[I]t is not possible to run a well-functioning two-tiered market, with some deregulated and some regulated units.”); see also Tucker, supra note 167, at 3–4 (discussing shadow markets). CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 112 This leads us to consider another likely critique from landlords in jurisdictions with no rent regulation or good cause eviction laws. Such landlords could object to the interference of government in their market. However, the RSP rests on solid legal and programmatic precedent.181 Operating residential rental housing in urban areas is a highly regulated enterprise, whether or not rent regulation applies. Governments must be finely attuned to the external effects of land uses, given the high levels of density in urban areas.182 Therefore, owners of such properties are familiar with government regulation in a number of contexts.183 Almost all owners are subject to building code regulations and most are subject to zoning constraints as to the type of building and size of buildings that are allowed.184 In addition, several states and many localities restrict owners’ rights to evict only for prescribed “good cause.”185 Finally, many states and localities restrict owners’ ability to convert units to condominium or cooperative status.186 Finally, there is no doubt that the RSP will come with administrative costs. My proposal suggests that, in order to ensure consistent statewide application, each state designate an agency as the regulatory authority for each of the localities that 181 See Block v. Hirsch, 256 U.S. 135 (1921) (upholding Washington D.C. rent regulation scheme from constitutional attack); Pennell v. City of San Jose, 485 U.S. 1 (1988) (following Block v. Hirsch); Rent Stabilization Ass’n v. Higgins, 83 N.Y.2d 156 (1993) (citing Block v. Hirsch as good law). 182 See Ellen & O’Flaherty, supra note 52, at 31 (noting that localities might be more likely to try to promote residential stability through regulation in dense “residential environments [where t]he development of trust and social capital among neighbors seems more critical”). 183 See Apgar 2004, supra note 5, at 10 (“[T]enant/landlord laws and regulations govern the obligation of the property owner to meet certain standards of service provision and process concerning . . . eviction . . . . [Also] zoning, building and health codes along with other land use regulations impose responsibilities on owners . . . or otherwise place limitations on the use of an owner occupied property.”). 184 See Baar, supra note 168, at 1234–35. 185 See Roisman, supra note 73, at 834–35. 186 See 15A AM. JUR. 2D Condominiums § 16. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 113 adopt the RSP. Said state agency would also supervise the RGB that sets annual cost based increases. The exact costs to state government in administering the RSP would depend on a variety of factors, including the number and population size of the localities which adopt the RSP, the number of complaints and disputes to be adjudicated and other factors. It is likely that there would be a fairly significant amount of resources needed at the commencement of the RSP; from then on a professional staff at the agency would likely suffice. Localities could consider funding the RSP through user fees assessed against landlords and/or tenants, or through general purpose tax revenues. When calculating whether to adopt the RSP, sophisticated states and localities would focus on the potential benefits in addition to the administrative costs. The benefits of the RSP would be increased stability for tenant households and the accompanying spillover benefits to the surrounding communities. These include an increase in citizen participation in the community, better maintenance of their houses, and lower rates of neighborhood crime.187 In conclusion, the goals served by the RSP—increasing tenant and neighborhood stability—outweigh the costs and potential inefficiencies of the program. VI. ALTERNATIVES TO THE RSP Happily, I am far from alone in concluding that the current state of housing policy needs substantial revision to assist rental and owner households. Below are three examples of innovative new approaches to housing policy formed in response to the current crisis. While all three offer some improvement over the current system, I argue that they all fall short of the RSP in terms of alleviating housing instability. A. Rental Insurance Robert Lerman & Aigne-Mary McKernan have promoted the 187 See supra Section II.C. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 114 development of a financial risk or hedge product, which would enable renters to buy protection against future rent increases, based on some composite index of rents in the applicable neighborhood or market.188 Their approach builds on the work of Robert Shiller, who assisted in developing markets which enable homeowners and other traders to purchase and sell insurance tied to reductions in area house prices.189 Lerman & McKernan seek to extend such a concept to renters. The authors argue that such an approach is preferable to rent regulations or rent subsidies. They cite the usual arguments against rent regulations, namely that such regulation reduces property owners’ incentives to maintain property and to invest in added housing thereby “inducing shortages and higher prices for uncontrolled units.” As to rent subsidies, the authors object to the fact that subsidies in gentrifying neighborhoods will exceed those in lower income areas. They argue that their approach “improves on rent control and some subsidy approaches by divorcing the compensation (for area rent increases) from the renter’s subsequent choice of locations.”190 The idea proposed by Lerman & McKernan has a number of elegant features. Most notably, after the market for such rental insurance is created and perfected, government’s role can be relatively minor. Indeed, regulating the market for such a product should be much less involved than the administrative role under the RSP in setting rent increases, monitoring compliance and settling disputes. Furthermore, it creates no incentives for conflict between landlords and tenants. For all its theoretical advantages, however, the proposed rental insurance product raises a number of unanswered questions and concerns. First, who would pay for such a product 188 See Robert I. Lerman & Signe-Mary McKernan, Promoting Neighborhood Improvement while Protecting Low Income Families, 8 URBAN INST., May 2007, available at http://www.urban.org/UploadedPDF/311457_ Promoting_Neighborhood.pdf. 189 See Robert Schiller, Mortgages of the Future, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 21, 2008, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2008/09/21/business/21view. html. 190 See Lerman & McKernan, supra note 188, at 2. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 115 for low and moderate-income households?191 Second, the complexity of the product proposed is worrisome.192 The product seems difficult to create: it requires an extremely accurate measure of rents down to a fairly granular level—zip code. It is questionable whether reliable data for this index currently exists. Even more problematic, the complexity of the product seems to limit its usefulness for the intended beneficiaries, at least those without a high degree of financial sophistication. As we have seen from the subprime mortgage example, devising complex financial products for low to moderate-income households regarding their housing situation is fraught with risk. In this case, the success of the insurance product depends on renters choosing the right amount of coverage—not an easy task. Perhaps these concerns can be addressed. For now, it suffices to say that the RSP is a more viable program. No new markets or inventions are needed and the households that are the intended beneficiaries will be protected by a legal system that is administered by a government agency specifically charged with its enforcement. B. Requiring Good Cause For Eviction In her recent article,193 Florence Roisman identifies the lack of restriction on landlords’ abilities to evict or fail to renew leases as the primary problem for tenants. She advocates for courts, through common law contract doctrines, to enact a requirement that landlords have good cause before evictions. She notes that protected tenancies should not be restricted to those 194 who can “negotiate long-term leases” but to all. Roisman clearly shares my goals of providing additional stability for rental households, however, she does not address 191 See Fennell & Roin, Controlling, supra note 175, at 19. See id. at 19-22 (attempting to develop the proposal that Lerman & McKernan sketched out, acknowledging a number of unanswered questions and logistical difficulties). 193 Roisman, supra note 73. 194 Id. at 829. 192 CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 116 whether or how tenants would be shielded from eviction resulting from an inability to pay for rent increases. The RSP incorporates Roisman’s central point by requiring as an essential component that landlords have good cause to evict or fail to renew a lease. The RSP goes further by addressing the economic side of the equation: specifically the RSP offers all tenants a certain degree of rental protection for ten years, and to those who are low- to moderate-income and rent burdened, a subsidy to cover the allowable increases.195 C. New Models of Homeownership Lee Ann Fennell of the University of Chicago Law School has offered one of the most creative proposals aimed at reforming the current model of homeownership, called Homeownership 2 or H2.0.196 H2.0 is designed to enable aspiring homebuyers to purchase a home but limit the extent of their investment (and risk of loss) to factors within the homeowner’s control. Specifically, H2.0 seeks to allocate to homeowners the profit and loss properly tied to the condition 195 There are of course other rental models that could be considered. One interesting example is that of Sweden, described in detail in One Nation’s Dream, Another’s Realty: Housing Justice In Sweden, 22 BROOK. J. INT’L L. 63, 94–96 (1996). In Sweden, the government plays a much more significant role in the rental market than in the U.S., significantly more than even those jurisdictions under rent control. Construction and operation of most rental housing in Sweden is financed by the government and therefore the rent setting process and admissions process is heavily controlled by the government as well. Among other aspects, Swedish tenants are protected from eviction by good cause requirements and prospective tenants obtain newer apartments by waiting list. Furthermore, “[r]ents are determined on an annual basis pursuant to negotiations between the municipal housing corporations and tenants’ associations.” Id. at 94–95. Kenn finds much to admire in the Swedish model, but the amount of subsidies and degree of governmental involvement required do not make it a good fit for the current political and economic system in the United States. See also Roisman, supra note 73, at 856 (“The provision of decent, affordable housing for poor people is not an area for private enterprise. It is a government responsibility . . . .”). 196 See Fennell, supra note 8. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 117 and improvements made to the house and site-specific factors they can control. The risk and reward attributable to local offsite factors (schools, crime rates, neighborhood amenities) as well as broader economic risks (real estate prices, economic cycles) would be purchased by a market of investors.197 Thus, Fennell envisions a new option for homebuyers—the right to purchase a home and keep the equity based on payments made and improvements to the house and site but to avoid the broader economic investment that is currently required.198 Fennell’s proposal has a great deal of promise. I believe that she accurately posits that a significant percentage of prospective homebuyers would be interested in exchanging some of the potential upside of their home investment for a product that limits the potential downside as well. This is especially likely in turbulent real estate market cycles such as the current one. Indeed, if it could be perfected, H2.0 could be the kind of tool that gets prospective buyers “off the sideline” as has been the common refrain among real estate professionals and many 197 See id. at 1072. As Fennell discusses, H2.0 is a variation on a more traditional shared equity or shared appreciation type of homeownership program. See id. In such a program, a public or private entity contributes part of the upfront cost of purchasing a home. In exchange, such investor entity shares in any future house appreciation. Public investors, usually municipal governments, use such appreciation to enable low to moderate income households to purchase the house when it is put up for re-sale. See id. at 1064–66. In Australia, a privately created product called the Equity Finance Mortgage uses future house appreciation to replace monthly payments on a second position loan that is made to enable the household to afford the downpayment. See Equity Finance Mortgage, http://www.efm.info/pdf/EFMBrochureV3.pdf (last visited Sept. 30, 2009). When the household sells the property or refinances, it must repay the principal balance of the second loan plus up to a 40% share of any increase in the value of the property. See id. Other intriguing proposals to revise the current model of homeownership include Robert Schiller’s idea of the continually adjusting mortgage. This mortgage product, to be offered by banks, would reduce defaults by automatically adjusting payments due each month according to fluctuations in the economic and real estate markets. See Robert Schiller, Mortgages of the Future, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 21, 2008, available at http://www.nytimes.com/ 2008/09/21/business/21view.html. 198 CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 118 economists in recent months. H2.0 has the additional promise of maintaining the economic incentives for homeowners to improve their property as well as the local conditions under their control. This adds a layer of sophistication to her proposal. However, H2.0 does not seek to address the crisis experienced by millions of households who are seeking more affordable and stable rental options.199 Indeed, by excluding rental housing from its purview, I fear that H2.0 continues the emphasis on homeownership as the Holy Grail for both household satisfaction and economic recovery. To achieve the balance between homeownership and rental programs, I would urge adoption of the RSP or other rental programs as a complement to H2.0. CONCLUSION Our current polices of prioritizing homeownership to the exclusion of the needs of rental households have failed. We as a society need to stop over subsidizing and promoting homeownership as the only model for successful American households. Changes to policy are particularly urgent now as millions of Americans have been forced from homeownership into rental housing as a result of the foreclosure crisis and the economic recession. The RSP offers one step towards reclaiming an equilibrium in government preferences between homeownership and renting. By enabling households to achieve stability while renting, the RSP provides benefits for those households and also their neighbors and larger communities. While the specific contours of the RSP are subject to further conversation, this paper makes 199 Fennell and her colleague Julie Roin, propose revising the incentives for both renters and homeowners. They seek to right size the incentives of both understaked households, renters and homeowners with no or negative equity, and “overstaked” homeowners who oppose sensible zoning ordinances and other neighborhood changes. See generally Fennell & Roin, Controlling, supra note 175. The authors urge that local governments have an important stake in such “right staking” and, subject to state constitutional constraints, engage in such efforts. CHASE REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 7:32 PM RETHINKING THE HOMEOWNERSHIP SOCIETY 119 clear that the conversation regarding our national housing policy needs to be amended to include the needs of renters. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS: RACIALIZED CONSUMER FRAUD & REVERSE REDLINING Linda E. Fisher This article, presented at Brooklyn Law School’s 2009 Sparer Public Interest Law Symposium on a panel entitled Stopping the Next Subprime Crisis, is part of a larger project of information and strategy-sharing among academics, policy analysts and attorneys involved in foreclosure and predatory lending prevention. The article marshals and analyzes evidence of discriminatory and deceptive marketing practices by subprime mortgage lenders and brokers. It also supports current proposals for policy reforms that could address the misuse of new marketing technologies in this context. INTRODUCTION The subprime meltdown created many casualties. Foremost among them are subprime borrowers themselves.1 While some Professor of Law, Seton Hall Law School. I would particularly like to thank Arielle Cohen of the National Consumer Law Center (formerly with the New Jersey Institute for Social Justice) for her assistance in researching the practices I describe in this article. I am also grateful to Marc Poirier for comments and suggestions on an earlier draft. 1 Michael Aleo & Pablo Svirsky, Foreclosure Fallout: The Banking Industry’s Attack on Disparate Impact Race Discrimination Claims Under the Fair Housing Act and the Equal Credit Opportunity Act, 18 B.U. PUB. INT. L.J. 1, 1–8 (2008). Subprime loans are generally considered those with an annual percentage rate (APR) on a first mortgage that is more than 3% above the comparable Treasury rate. This figure is taken from the Federal Reserve’s definition of high rate loans, which has developed into a shorthand 121 FISHER REVISED.DOC 122 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY commentators disparage these borrowers for defrauding lenders by misstating their incomes, the reality is much more complicated: evidence is mounting that certain subprime lenders deliberately sought out financially vulnerable borrowers for deceptive sales tactics and predatory mortgage loans. In many cases, loan officers and mortgage brokers—without borrowers’ knowledge—concocted false income and assets and ordered inflated appraisals, all to obtain mortgages generating large profits for themselves.2 For some lenders, these techniques were standard operating practice.3 There was little incentive to working definition of subprime loans. See Alan M. White, Borrowing While Black: Applying Fair Lending Laws to Risk-Based Mortgage Pricing, 60 S.C. L. REV. 677, 682 (2009) (citing 12 C.F.R. § 203.4(a)(12) and Robert B. Avery et al., Higher-Priced Home Lending and the 2005 HMDA Data, FED. RES. BULL. (Fed. Reserve Bd., Wash., D.C.), Sept. 8, 2006 at A123-24, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/2006/hmda/ bull06hmda.pdf); see also Aleo & Svirsky, supra, at 1–8 (setting forth a comprehensive definition of subprime mortgages). My point here is not that all subprime lenders engaged in predatory lending, or that subprime lending is equivalent to predatory lending, but rather that predatory lending was quite prevalent among subprime lenders. The distinction between the two has been explored at length elsewhere. See NAT’L PREDATORY LENDING TASK FORCE, U.S. DEP’T. OF HOUS. AND URBAN DEV. & U.S. TREASURY DEP’T., CURBING PREDATORY HOME MORTGAGE LENDING 17 (2000), available at http://www.huduser.org/ Publications/pdf/treasrpt.pdf [hereinafter PREDATORY LENDING REPORT]; JAMES H. CARR & LOPA KOLLURI, FANNIE MAE FOUNDATION, PREDATORY LENDING: AN OVERVIEW 5–6 (2001), available at http://www.knowledge plex.org/kp/text_document_summary/article/relfiles/hot_topics/Carr-Kolluri. pdf; Creola Johnson, Fight Blight: Cities Sue to Hold Lenders Responsible for the Rise in Foreclosures and Abandoned Properties, 2008 UTAH L. REV. 1169, 1174–75 (2008). 2 See infra text accompanying notes 69–81. Loan officers, mortgage brokers and other originators were responsible at the ground level for working with borrowers and preparing loan applications. See FINDING A MORTGAGE FOR YOUR NEW HOME: BANKS VS. MORTGAGE BROKERS, available at http://homebuying.about.com/cs/mortgagearticles/a/home_ lenders.htm. These terms are often used interchangeably. See infra note 44 (discussing the various ways in which originators and banks worked together to fund mortgages). 3 For instance, Ameriquest and its affiliate Argent seem to have followed FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 123 underwrite carefully because the funding lenders rarely kept the loans in their own portfolios, but rather assigned them to upstream purchasers for packaging into pools of mortgagebacked securities.4 Many of those perpetrating these deceptions employed target marketing techniques to generate business. “Target marketing” refers to the practice of developing profiles of desired consumers and using those profiles to designate an audience for a product these practices. See infra note 69 and accompanying text. 4 See Kathleen C. Engel & Patricia McCoy, Turning a Blind Eye: Wall Street Finance of Predatory Lending, 75 FORDHAM L. REV. 2039, 2040–49 (2007); Christopher L. Peterson, Predatory Structured Finance, 28 CARDOZO L. REV. 2185, 2207–13 (2007); Patricia McCoy & Elizabeth Renuart, Legal Infrastructure of Subprime and Nontraditional Home Mortgages 34–40 (Joint Ctr. for Hous. Studies, Working Paper No. UCC08-5, 2008), available at http://www.jchs.harvard.edu/publications/finance/understanding_consumer_cr edit/papers/ucc08_5_mccoy_renuart.pdf; Benjamin J. Keys et al., Did Securitization Lead to Lax Screening? 3 (Dec. 2008) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1093137) (concluding that portfolios that are more likely to be securitized default around 10–25% more often than those of a similar risk profile group with a lower probability of securitization); Amiyatosh Purnanandan, Originate-to-Distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis 2–3 (Apr. 27, 2009) (unpublished manuscript, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1167786). For an explanation of the structure of securitized trusts, see NOMURA FIXED INCOME RESEARCH, NOMURA SEC. INT’L, INC., MBS BASICS (2006), available at http://www.securitization.net/pdf/Nomura/MBSBasics_31Mar06. pdf and Charles K. Whitehead, The Evolution of Debt: Covenants, The Credit Market, and Corporate Governance, 34 J. CORP. L. 641, 655–56 (2009) (“Banks . . . became less interested in holding loans to their maturity in light of the growing ability to enhance returns by selling loan interests to others.”). I use the past tense to refer to subprime lending because most subprime lending has ceased in the past couple of years. See Peter M. Zorn et al., From FHA to Subprime and Back, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract= 1365401. For example, twenty of the largest twenty-five subprime lenders are no longer operating: some filed bankruptcy, some failed or are in receivership, while others were purchased by larger entities. See John Dunbar & David Donald, Who’s Behind the Financial Meltdown?, CENTER FOR PUBLIC INTEGRITY, May 6, 2009, http://www.publicintegrity.org/ investigations/economic_meltdown/articles/entry/1286/. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 124 pitch.5 Employing techniques ranging from sophisticated demographic analyses of defined geographic areas to arrangements with local brokers in low-income urban neighborhoods, these subprime lenders focused on borrowers with little knowledge of mortgage lending in general and their own financial options in particular.6 In fact, many subprime borrowers apparently were sufficiently creditworthy to qualify for prime loans, but were steered into higher cost subprime loans anyway.7 Other lenders—or the brokers working with them—specifically targeted borrowers already in financial distress and foreclosure for refinancing.8 Mortgage loans with unjustifiably high interest rates and higher principal balances increased the stream of income for lenders and investors, and resulted in larger commissions for loan officers and brokers; higher points and fees added to the bottom line. This profit 5 See infra Part I. This article focuses on the use of target marketing techniques in the promotion of subprime loans in communities of color. Historically, communities of color lacked access to mainstream financial institutions and knowledge of the mortgage market. See Raymond H. Brescia, The Worst of Times: Perspectives on and Solutions for the Subprime Mortgage Crisis, 2 ALB. GOV’T L. REV. 164, 172 (2009) (citing DAN IMMERGLUCK, CREDIT TO THE COMMUNITY: COMMUNITY REINVESTMENT AND FAIR LENDING POLICY IN THE UNITED STATES 87–108 (2004)) (analyzing discriminatory roots of the subprime crisis and viability of reverse redlining claims under the Fair Housing Act); Benjamin Howell, Comment, Exploiting Race and Space: Concentrated Subprime Lending as Housing Discrimination, 94 CAL. L. REV. 101, 128–30 (2006). Many homebuying and mortgage schemes have been perpetrated on residents of black neighborhoods through the years, with their form varying based on conditions at the time. E.g., BERYL SATTER, FAMILY PROPERTIES: RACEL, REAL ESTATE, AND THE EXPLOITATION OF BLACK URBAN AMERICA (2009) (recounting contract buying schemes in Chicago in the last century). 7 See CARR & KOLLURI, supra note 1, at 7 (“Credit quality alone . . . does not fully explain the extreme reliance of black households on the subprime market. Further research by Freddie Mac reports that as much as 35 percent of borrowers in the subprime market could qualify for prime market loans. Fannie Mae estimates that number closer to 50 percent.”); White, supra note 1, at 688–89; infra, text accompanying note 50. 8 See infra note 103. 6 FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 125 making ultimately was detrimental to everyone, but perhaps most of all to the borrowers, a high percentage of whom are or will soon be in foreclosure.9 To further complicate the picture, African-American and Latino borrowers took out disproportionately high rates of subprime loans as compared to white borrowers.10 Of course, not all subprime lending was predatory, but the incidence of predatory practices such as those described here was considerably higher for subprime as compared to prime lending.11 The available evidence bears out this conclusion.12 A number of national studies, controlling for risk factors like income and/or credit score, have substantiated the strong correlation between race and subprime lending.13 Unsurprisingly, 9 See Associated Press, Mortgage Delinquencies Hit Record High in Q1, N.J. STAR LEDGER, May 28, 2009 (“A record 12 percent of homeowners with a mortgage are behind in their payments or in foreclosure . . . . At the same time, almost half of all adjustable-rate loans made to borrowers with shaky credit were past due or in foreclosure.”); Shane M. Sherlund, The Past, Present, and Future of Subprime Mortgages 17 (Fed. Res. Bd., Working Paper No. 2008-63, 2008) available at http://www.federalreserve. gov/Pubs/feds/2008/200863/200863pap.pdf. (“[M]ore recently originated subprime loans are more likely to default, well ahead of their first mortgage rate resets, and less likely to prepay (i.e., to refinance).”). 10 Brescia, supra note 6, at 173. 11 See PREDATORY LENDING REPORT, supra note 1. It is not my intent to elide the distinction between predatory and subprime lending, but it is not a primary focus of this paper. See supra note 1. 12 See infra text accompanying notes 70–90. The practices described occurred almost exclusively with subprime and Alt-A loans, not prime loans. See David Reiss, Regulation of Subprime and Predatory Lending, INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF HOUSING AND HOME, available at http://works.bepress.com/cgi/viewcontent.cg?.article=1027&context=david_ reiss. 13 See White, supra note 1, at 687–89; DEBBIE GRUENSTEIN BOCIAN ET AL., CTR. FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, UNFAIR LENDING: THE EFFECT OF RACE AND ETHNICITY ON THE PRICE OF SUBPRIME MORTGAGES 3 (2006) available at http://www.responsiblelending.org/mortgage-lending/researchanalysis/unfair-lending-the-effect-of-race-and-ethnicity-on-the-price-ofsubprime-mortgages.html (“Our study analyzed subprime home loan prices charged to different racial and ethnic groups while controlling for the effects of credit scores, loan-to-value ratios, and other underwriting factors . . . . FISHER REVISED.DOC 126 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY minority borrowers were significantly more likely than white borrowers both to work with mortgage brokers and to take out high-cost subprime loans.14 This correlation itself suggests discrimination under either disparate treatment or disparate impact theories; that is, African-Americans and Latinos were either intentionally singled out for the worst loans or have suffered disproportionately from the effects of facially neutral lending policies.15 The phenomenon of singling out minorities for Our findings show that, for most types of subprime loans, African-American and Latino borrowers are at greater risk of receiving higher-rate loans than white borrowers, even after controlling for legitimate risk factors.”); see PREDATORY LENDING REPORT, supra note 1, at 3 (“HUD found that, even after controlling for neighborhood income (although without controlling [sic] for credit history or risk), people living in predominantly African-American communities refinance in the subprime market much more often than people living in predominantly white communities.”); NAT’L CMTY. REINVESTMENT COAL., INCOME IS NO SHIELD AGAINST RACIAL DIFFERENCES IN LENDING II: A COMPARISON OF HIGH-COST LENDING IN AMERICA’S METROPOLITAN AND RURAL AREAS 3 (2008), available at http://www.ncrc.org/images/stories/ mediaCenter_reports/ncrc%20metro%20study%20race%20and%20income%2 0disparity%20july%2007.pdf (“[A]fter controlling for creditworthiness and other housing market factors, minorities are receiving a disproportionately large amount of high-cost loans.”); see generally MARGERY AUSTIN TURNER & FELICITY SKIDMORE, THE URBAN INSTITUTE, MORTGAGE LENDING DISCRIMINATION: A REVIEW OF EXISTING EVIDENCE (1999) available at http://www.urban.org/UploadedPDF/mortgage_lending.pdf (reviewing existing studies and evidence). 14 [A] significant factor causing minorities to pay higher mortgage rates is their greater likelihood of getting a mortgage through a broker rather than by dealing directly with lenders . . . . [O]ne-half to two-thirds of the pricing disparity between whites and minority borrowers results from the greater likelihood that minority borrowers end up getting mortgages from subprime lenders . . . .[Minority borrowers] are more likely to borrow from lenders that specialize in subprime mortgages . . . and more likely to borrow through brokers interacting with wholesale lenders. White, supra note 1, at 687–88. 15 This article does not delve into fine points of the doctrine of disparate treatment or disparate impact discrimination, which others have assessed at length. See, e.g., Timothy C. Lambert, Comment, Fair Marketing: Challenging Pre-Application Lending Practices, 87 GEO. L.J. 2181 (1999). FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 127 predatory loans has been dubbed “reverse redlining.”16 This is a reference to an inversion of the older practice of “redlining,” or excluding minority neighborhoods altogether from mortgage lending.17 Several state and local governments—in addition to nonprofits and private plaintiffs—have sued subprime lenders and brokers for engaging in these activities, alleging violations of the federal Fair Housing and Equal Credit Opportunity Acts and, in many cases, state consumer fraud statutes.18 The term racialized consumer fraud, as used in this article, refers to the practice of aiming the most deceptive or unconscionable lending practices at minorities. This article focuses not only on evidence of this phenomenon, or on the link between race and consumer fraud, but also on the extent to 16 See, e.g., City of Baltimore v. Wells Fargo Bank, N.A., No. L-08-62, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 56794, at *1 (D. Md. July 2, 2009) (motion to dismiss denied July 2, 2009); City of Baltimore v. Wells Fargo Bank, N.A., __ F. Supp. 2d __, 2010 WL 46401 (D. Md., Jan. 6, 2010) (granting motion to dismiss); see also Johnson, supra note 1, at 118127 (examining costs of foreclosures to cities, and current legal responses, including nuisance suits filed by Cleveland and Buffalo, as well as the Baltimore litigation against Wells Fargo). 17 Assocs. Home Equity Servs. v. Troup, 778 A.2d 529, 537 (App. Div. 2001) (“The term ‘redlining’ is derived from the actual practice of drawing a red line around designated areas in which credit is to be denied. . . . Congress has reported that ‘reverse redlining’ . . . [is] the targeting of residents of those same communities for credit on unfair terms.”) (citations omitted); see also Howell, supra note 6, at 105–16 (recounting history of “America’s Racial Geography,” including redlining). 18 See NAACP v. Ameriquest Mortgage Co., No. SACV 07-0794 AG, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 66117 (C.D. Cal. Jan. 12, 2009); Wells Fargo, 2009 U.S. Dist. Lexis at 56794; Commonwealth v. H&R Block, Inc., No. 20082474BLS1, 2008 Mass. Super. LEXIS 427 (Super. Ct. Nov. 25, 2008). In particular, the litigation between the city of Baltimore and Wells Fargo has received a great deal of recent attention because of its revelations of the sort of broker and loan officer conduct that is described here. See Julie Bykowicz, City Can Proceed with Wells Fargo Lawsuit, BALTIMORE SUN, July 3, 2009, at 10A (stating that federal district court denied motion to dismiss on July 2, 2009). Recently, the State of Illinois filed a similar suit against Wells Fargo. Amy Merrick, Illinois Sues Wells Fargo Over Mortgage Discrimination, WALL ST. J., July 31, 2009, available at http://online.wsj.com/article/SB12 4906504187697487.html#. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 128 which target marketing techniques enabled these practices to proliferate. Targeting did so by allowing the worst subprime lenders to concentrate on consumers in narrowly defined geographic or demographic niches and thus increased the efficiency of predatory lending, afflicting entire neighborhoods.19 For example, patterns of residential segregation in this country allow marketers to search by census tract, segments of a zip code, or similar criteria to derive lists of potential customers that strongly correlate with race, since residents of a single neighborhood tend to be of the same race.20 In other words, address often serves as a proxy for race. This paper also suggests a possible link between the Furman Center’s findings, as presented to this conference, of higher rates of subprime lending to all borrowers living in predominantly minority neighborhoods21 and the practices described herein; that is, when majority minority areas are singled out and blanketed with solicitations for predatory subprime loans, white residents of the neighborhood can fall prey to these loans as well.22 19 See Alex Kotlowitz, All Boarded Up, N.Y. TIMES MAG., Mar. 8, 2009, at 28; Jenny Schuetz et al., Neighborhood Effects of Concentrated Mortgage Foreclosures, 14–15 (Furman Ctr. for Real Estate and Urban Policy, Working Paper 08–03, 2008), available at http://www.furmancenter. org/files/foreclosures08-03.pdf. 20 See Ruth D. Peterson & Lauren J. Krivo, Race, Residence and Violent Crime: A Structure of Inequality, 57 U. KAN. L. REV. 903, 908 (2009) (“[I]n 2000, an average of 65.2% of metropolitan blacks (or whites) would have to move to a different neighborhood to achieve an even residential distribution.”); see also DOUGLAS S. MASSEY & NANCY A. DENTON, AMERICAN APARTHEID: SEGREGATION AND THE MAKING OF THE UNDERCLASS 191 (1993). 21 Vicki Been et al., The High Cost of Segregation: Exploring Racial Disparities in High-Cost Lending, 36 FORDHAM URB. L.J. 361, 380–81 (2009); see also Kathe Newman & Elvin Wyly, Geographies of Mortgage Market Segmentation: The Case of Essex County, New Jersey, 19 HOUSING STUD. 53 (2004). 22 Been et al., supra note 21, at 382 (“[B]lack and white borrowers are more likely to get a high-cost loan when they are buying a home in a census tract that has a high proportion of blacks. Blacks and whites, in other words, appear to be at a mortgage-cost disadvantage by buying homes in neighborhoods with more black residents.”). FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 129 This targeting did not always involve a conscious motive to discriminate. There is a distinction between target marketing that explicitly uses race as a criterion and that which uses geography. A further distinction exists between intentionally using geography as a proxy for race and targeting low-income urban neighborhoods, though both created inequitable results in an entirely predictable fashion, with minority borrowers receiving much worse loans than similar white borrowers.23 Part I of this article describes the range of current target market techniques and their adaptation to the subprime lending context. Part II provides evidence of racialized consumer fraud in subprime lending, relying on evidence obtained by counsel in reverse redlining and consumer fraud lawsuits, accounts published by the media, and reports I have gathered as a practitioner in the field. Finally, Part III briefly examines selected lawsuits challenging these practices that have recently survived motions to dismiss or resulted in preliminary injunctive relief. Given the evidence, this article argues for increased enforcement of fair housing and lending laws in the mortgage lending context. In addition, consumer financial services reforms must take into account the pernicious use of new targeting technologies and develop means to stanch it. I. TARGET MARKETING A. Introduction In recent decades marketing techniques have become quite sophisticated. Marketers can identify audiences most likely to purchase products ranging from retail goods to financial services. By dividing the population into niches according to characteristics such as household composition, income, age, employment, consumer spending, area of residence, and language spoken, marketers can pinpoint potential customers 23 This article does not engage in a full doctrinal analysis of disparate treatment and disparate impact fair housing/fair lending claims regarding mortgage lending. For that analysis, see Lambert, supra note 15, at 2193– 97. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 130 with great refinement.24 Financial institutions use this process of market segmentation,25 as it is called, to solicit those most likely to apply for various types of mortgages or credit cards.26 Companies typically compile lists of target customers by first culling their own records to determine who bought similar products from them in the past.27 Next, they purchase reports on these individuals from private services such as credit bureaus that, in turn, have mined information from public records and other sources to build a profile of each individual in the database.28 That profile frequently includes residential information broken down as finely as ZIP + 4.29 The dataset is 24 For example, the major credit bureaus offer these services. See Trans Union Corp. v. FTC, 81 F.3d 229 (D.C. Cir. 1996); Experian List Services INSOURCE Enhancement and List Services, http://www.experian.com/ products/insource.html (last visited Sept. 12, 2009); TransUnion Business: Prescreens and Lists, Sales Lead List Software, http://www.transunion.com/ corporate/business/serviceSolutions/marketingServices/prescreensLists.page (last visited Sept. 12, 2009). Yahoo also offers marketing services for businesses. Advertising Your Business with Yahoo! Search Marketing, http://sem.smallbusiness.yahoo.com/searchenginemarketing/ (last visited Sept. 12, 2009). 25 See ART WEINSTEIN, HANDBOOK OF MARKET SEGMENTATION: STRATEGIC TARGETING FOR BUSINESS AND TECHNOLOGY FIRMS (3rd Ed. 2004); Ross D. Petty et al., Regulating Target Marketing and Other RaceBased Advertising Practices, 8 MICH. J. RACE & L. 335 (2003). 26 See Dennis Gale, Subprime and Predatory Mortgage Refinancing: Information Technology, Credit Scoring and Vulnerable Borrowers 9–10 (Fisher Ctr. for Real Estate and Urban Econ., Conference Paper C01-001, 2001), available at http://urbanpolicy.berkeley.edu/pdf/Gale.pdf (analyzing effects of increasingly sophisticated technology, including “geodemographic marketing tools” on predatory lending in early years of this decade). 27 Brad Stone, The Debt Trap: Banks Mine Data and Woo Troubled Borrowers, N.Y. TIMES, October 22, 2008, fig. 1; Lambert supra note 15, at 2187–92 (1999) (describing these marketing techniques and assessing applicability of fair housing and fair lending claims against their discriminatory misuse). 28 Lambert, supra note 15, at 2187–88; see also Daniel J. Solove, Data Mining and the Security-Liberty Debate, 75 U. CHI. L. REV. 343, 355–59 (2008) (discussing constitutional issues with respect to information collection for data mining). 29 ZIP + 4 is a Post Office system of adding four additional digits after a FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 131 then analyzed to identify additional common characteristics of the pool of purchasers.30 After purchasing a new dataset of additional consumers, the companies score individuals in the new set according to their attractiveness as targets for future solicitations.31 For example, an entity named Claritas, which is affiliated with Nielsen (best known for its television audience surveys), sells demographic information that can be very finely sliced according to a purchaser’s preferences.32 One of its products, suggestively called P$YCLE, divides people into fifty-eight segments, each with a memorable name, including: 29. Retirement Ready—The nearly-retired Americans in this segment enjoy comfortable lifestyles on middle-class incomes. Although not asset-rich, members of Retirement Ready do invest in real estate and variable-rate annuities, and they’ve built up enough home equity to take out second mortgages and home equity loans . . . .33 50. Urban Essentials—With their lower-income wages and low levels of assets, they rank at the bottom for savings, investments and retirement accounts. And many of these urban renters go without auto, life or medical insurance as well. A racially diverse mix of young, urban singles, couples and families, this group is generally limited in its financial behavior to taking out student and zip code to break the area down into smaller segments to facilitate mail delivery. See http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/ZIP_code; see also Direct Marketing, Mail, Tele, Email and Fax Marketing Programs, www.directmarketinglists.com/contentpages/mortgage.htm (last visited Sept. 18, 2009) [hereinafter Direct Marketing]. 30 Stone, supra note 27, at fig.1. 31 Id. 32 Claritas—P$YCLE Segmentation System, http://www.claritas.com/ claritas/Default.jsp?ci=3&si=4&pn=psycle (last visited Sept. 10, 2009). P$YCLE data is provided in a format that is designed to easily combine credit information from the major credit bureaus and other information sources to allow carefully targeted marketing. Id. 33 CLARITAS, IXPRESS FINANCIAL INSIGHT STANDARD COMPONENTS 162 (2007), available at www.claritas.com/collateral/data/col_ixpress_financial_ db.pdf. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 132 personal loans and using debit cards at ATMs. . . .34 54. City Strivers—The majority of residents are under 34 years old, have lower-middle incomes and have incomeproducing assets only a quarter of the national average. Many are in debt paying off student, car or personal loans—and with their modest bank accounts, they don’t pursue long-term investments, retirement savings and life insurance.35 Given the potential for misuse, segmentation becomes problematic when race, or proxies for race, are incorporated into defined categories. For instance, the last of P$YCLE’s niches clearly references predominantly minority urban populations: 58. Bottom-Line Blues—No segment has fewer incomeproducing assets, and few rank lower when it comes to income or home ownership. Concentrated in inner-city neighborhoods, the segment is the address for mostly young, multi-ethnic singles and single-parent families living in low-cost apartments.36 While ethnic segmenting is not illegal in itself, and can serve seemingly legitimate purposes,37 it can be discriminatory when combined with the other practices.38 34 Id. at 150. Id. 36 Id. at 151. Arielle Cohen of the New Jersey Institute for Justice calls this phenomenon “virtual redlining.” Correspondence from Arielle Cohen, N.J. Inst. for Justice, to Linda E. Fisher, Professor of Law, Seton Hall Law Sch. (September 23, 2008) (on file with author). This term alludes to the use of information technology to cordon off demographic segments and deny them the best credit opportunities. Id. 37 See, e.g., Target Market News, http://www.targetmarketnews.com (last visited Aug. 27, 2009) (calling itself “The Black Consumer Market Authority,” which serves as a conduit for products aimed at the black community). I do not single out Claritas as an example of a particularly bad actor—their services seem typical. See sources cited supra note 24. 38 See infra text accompanying notes 39–67. 35 FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 133 B. Target Marketing of Mortgages As elaborated below, smaller scale, but similar, targeting operations serve mortgage lenders exclusively and provide consumer mortgage data to lenders and mortgage brokers. Public records including recent home sales are merged with mortgage data so that purchasers can identify prospective customers for home equity loans or second mortgages.39 These entities sell targeting lists containing name, address, date of sale, current market value, loan amount, interest rate, credit score, and foreclosure status. These lists may also offer telemarketing scripts.40 Some combine neighborhood demographic and credit 39 See Direct Marketing, supra note 29. First Mortgage File. This file contains homeowner information dating back as early as the [sic] late 1988—over 50 million properties spread across 50 states. From this database, selections can be made on mortgage amount, origination date, lendable equity, lender name and current home values. This database is primarily used to identify homeowners with equity in their property that are candidates for home equity loans. Id. The company’s “Mortgage Profiling Credit Data” includes “Homeowner Mortgage Leads,” described in relevant part as follows: Sub-Prime: Sub-Prime auto prospects also make good home loan refinance candidates. They are aware that their credit is not perfect and are more flexible when it comes to interest rates, points, and loan fees they are willing to pay to obtain financing. Id. 40 See id. Another entity called Best Rate Referrals also sells mortgage scripts for telemarketers pitching targeted loans: Our mortgage lead generation system and telemarketing mortgage scripts have helped numerous clients increase their business nationwide through telemarketing . . . Quick Mortgage Scripts: Our telemarketing mortgage scripts prompt immediate interest in the homeowner and produce results. These mortgage scripts are perfect for loan officers and telemarketers. We have scripts for all types of mortgage marketing campaigns such as reverse mortgage, refinance, debt consolidation, ARMs, and real estate scripts. Order today and receive a free mortgage lead sheet. . . . FHA / VA Streamline Mortgage Script Only $4.95 FISHER REVISED.DOC 134 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY data to create a credit profile for similar localities sharing chosen characteristics.41 Thus, racial targeting can be easily accomplished without knowing the race of individuals, given the strong correlation between geography and race.42 On an even smaller scale, mortgage brokers also engage in target marketing. They originated—or created—the majority of mortgages in this country in the past decade, with even higher percentages of subprime originations.43 Many subprime lenders Mortgage Loan Modification Script Only $4.95 Mortgage Loan Modification Script Only $4.95 Reverse Mortgage Script Only $4.95 Refinance—Sub-Prime/Debt Consolidation Only $4.95 Refinance—Sub-Prime/Debt Consolidation Only $4.95 Refinance—ARM Script Only $4.95 Real Estate Lead Script Only $4.95 Real Estate Lead Script Only $4.95 . . . Mortgage Script Rebuttals: Mortgage Script Rebuttals are essential for generating interested mortgage prospects. Through our many years of experience we have fine tuned rebuttals for every response to spark interest in the prospect . . . . 2-Step Mortgage Lead Generation System Only $99.95 . . . Hiring & Training Mortgage Telemarketers Only $99.95 . . . We include everything you need to start generating mortgage leads your first day of operation. Telemarketing scripts, http://www.bestratereferrals.com/consulting.html (last visited Sept. 18, 2009) (emphasis in original). 41 Direct Marketing, supra note 29. The Sinclair Company, for instance, informs customers: “[b]y combining summarized credit statistics with other demographic selections you can identify the best candidates for your special offer.” Id. But it also warns: “[l]ists developed with statistics must be used in a positive or inclusive manner. The information cannot be used to deny or exclude customers from any offer.” Id. 42 See supra text accompanying note 20. 43 See KEITH ERNST ET AL., CTR. FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, STEERED WRONG: BROKERS, BORROWERS, AND SUBPRIME LOANS 6 (2008), available at http://www.responsiblelending.org/mortgage-lending/research-analysis/ steered-wrong-brokers-borrowers-and-subprime-loans.pdf. While mortgage brokers are active across the entire credit spectrum, they have played a major role in the rapid growth of the subprime mortgage market. . . . This growth was driven by the willingness of FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 135 worked primarily with brokers, rather than employing their own loan officers to originate loans.44 Through their wholesale lending divisions, the lenders relied on a variety of arrangements to fund loans originated by brokers.45 Brokers were paid with commissions or other premiums.46 The brokers in turn employed numerous methods to find customers, including targeted techniques such as those previously described.47 Notably, they subprime lenders to rely on third-party originators. Rather than build brick and mortar storefronts, subprime lenders have recruited brokers and, to a lesser degree, correspondent lenders to market and originate their loans. Together, the loans originated by these thirdparty originators are described as “wholesale” loans. . . . By 2006, . . . estimates from trade publications reported that such loans accounted for 63 to 81 percent of all subprime loans. Id. 44 Id. Lenders would reach out to brokers in a number of different ways, including online business. Interview with Jon Steingraber, Realtor, in Newark, N.J. (Sept. 2008). In some cases, lenders would advertise the availability of mortgages with specified terms to borrowers meeting certain profiles; brokers would respond if they had contact with a borrower meeting the criteria. Id. 45 See Dominick A. Mazzagetti, Dealing with Mortgage Loan Brokers: Legal and Practical Issues, 114 BANKING L.J. 923, 932 (1997). This excerpt describes the varieties of lender/broker (often referred to as “originator”) relationships, including: Category 1: The lender purchases whole loans after closing. The lender provides little or no input during the origination process. Category 2: The lender purchases whole loans after closing but has substantial input in underwriting, compliance, and documentation. Category 3: The lender ‘table funds’ loans originated and closed in the name of the originator. Category 4: The lender ‘table funds’ loans originated and closed in the name of the lender. Category 5: The lender becomes involved in loans immediately after application, issues commitments in its own name, and closes the loans in its own name. Id. 46 See infra text accompanying note 99. 47 On September 23, 2008, Arielle Cohen posted an inquiry on LinkedIn—“How do mortgage brokers get leads?”—and received these responses: FISHER REVISED.DOC 136 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY also depended heavily on local resources, such as realtors and neighborhood word-of-mouth.48 Lenders could also choose to do 1. Hi. You can do title searches with title companies. Just give them the criteria for the type of geography, tax liens, foreclosures, loan amounts, lender, even Spanish speakers, loan origination dates etc. They can usually do a detailed search for free. Of course they expect your business [sic]. 2. I’ve used leads generated from databases with homeowner information, along with those that contained credit information. I’m not sure the exact type of data you are looking for but feel free to contact me with any specific questions you may have. 3. I agree with the above responses . . . . Most of the mortgage brokers and loan officers that I work with get their leads/referrals from realtors. However, I am also a great source of leads for them... my company provides leads based on a number of variables and criteria and are already scrubbed through the DNC [do not call] list. These databases utilize category searches based on zip codes, existing lender information, current interest rate and loan types, etc. 4. This is one of the biggest mailing list suppliers in the country: http://www.usadata.com/?gclid=CKvs7uiI45UCFQgRFQodixHGfQ [.] You can refine the search list as much as you want. The more detailed list you want the more the list will cost. Meaning if you want a list of men and women the price might be X. But if you want a list of men and women between 25-35 the list might cost you XXX. A lot of information can come with the list and it costs money for each additional item. I am interested in what your [sic] investigating. Don’t you work for a non-profit group. 5. At height of the market the most successful mortgage brokers were getting the majority of their leads from strong relationships with realtors. Although the amount of sales activity in almost every market has decreased this is still the case. However, in this environment you will need to make sure to develop a strong lender network in order to capitalize on those relationships. It will also be imperative to affiliate yourself with an FHA lender, as I believe this will fill the void of the sub-prime business. In regards to using databases, I have had clients that have been successful using leads from title companies and lead generation companies. You can also combine these lists with a refractive dialer, to maximize the results. Posting of Arielle Cohen to LinkedIn profile page, http://www.linkedin.com (Sept. 23, 2008) (on file with the author). 48 See id. In my own experience litigating predatory lending cases, the brokers involved had connected with the borrower through local FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 137 business predominantly with brokers in selected neighborhoods. The targeting techniques described in this article made identification of those brokers simple. C. Targeting of African-American and Latino Borrowers for Subprime Mortgages As described above, mortgage brokers played a particularly pivotal role in subprime lending to minorities during the peak years of subprime lending.49 In addition to obtaining lists of potential customers in a designated area, the brokers utilized ties to local institutions and informal networks to tailor their sales pitches to residents’ perceived preferences and affiliations.50 Brokers’ neighborhood ties gave them direct access to potential customers who might not respond as readily to direct mail or telemarketing solicitations. Moreover, subprime brokers frequently were of the same race as most residents of the neighborhoods in which they worked, increasing the likelihood that they would be trusted.51 The limited financial options available to most black borrowers created vulnerability to these pitches, augmenting their attractiveness.52 Moreover, borrowers’ neighborhood networks. See, e.g., Complaint at ¶ 31, Gibson v. Bethea, No. L–5364–08 (N.J. Super. Ct. Law Div, Essex County Ct. 2008); Ted Sherman, Investors File Lawsuit Alleging Mortgage Con, N.J. STAR LEDGER, July 1, 2008. 49 See supra text accompanying notes 1538. 50 I was involved in a case in which the pastor of a church was himself a mortgage broker peddling subprime loans to parishioners and others. Pitman v. Stroedecke, et al., No. ESX-L-4083 (Sup. Ct. of N.J., Essex County, 2004). In other cases, local real estate developers worked hand in hand with mortgage brokers to convince local homebuyers to trust them, because they shared the same race and/or religion. E.g., Gibson Complaint, supra note 48, at ¶ 36; see also Philip Shishkin, When Rescue Means Eviction, WALL ST. J., Feb. 25, 2009 (featuring a case I litigated in New Jersey and recounting other cases around the country in which real estate brokers and developers gained the trust of homeowners in trouble, bought their homes, and defrauded them). 51 See Barkley v. Olympia Mortgage Co., No. 04-CV-875, 2007 WL 2437810, at *11 (E.D.N.Y. Aug. 22, 2007); Hargraves v. Capital City Mortgage Corp., 140 F. Supp. 2d 7, 21–22 (D.D.C. 2000). 52 See Dorothy A. Brown, Shades of the American Dream, 87 WASH U. FISHER REVISED.DOC 138 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY lack of financial sophistication also increased the likelihood that they would trust and believe salespeople who seemed genuinely concerned for their welfare. When the homeowners were facing bankruptcy or foreclosure, desperation often overrode their better judgment.53 In one variation, predatory property flippers, working with mortgage brokers and others, would solicit first-time minority homebuyers with “one-stop shopping” schemes that involved purchasing and financing sales of substandard homes.54 The flippers make false promises to the buyers and misrepresent the condition and cost of the homes. The brokers and their coconspirators then put the borrowers into predatory loans. Both use the targeting techniques described in this article to lure in unsuspecting buyers. A typical example is described in Barkley v. United Homes.55 First, the flippers used targeted advertising 56 “featuring minority consumers.” They also “placed ads in the Caribbean Life community newspaper that serves the West Indian immigrant community, while not advertising in community papers that are part of the same newspaper chain but serve primarily white neighborhoods.”57 Finally, they used “race-conscious outreach strategies” such as pairing salesmen L. R. (forthcoming 2010) (manuscript at 20, 4950, available at http://www.law.emory.edu/fileadmin/faculty_documents/dabrown7/Shades_La w_Review_Version.doc_compatability_Mode_.pdf) (discussing [at n. 58 & 71] reasons why black renters have been less likely to apply for mortgages than whites, and why, when investing, blacks have often preferred to invest conservatively in real estate as opposed to stocks or bonds). 53 This has frequently been my own experience, as well as that of consumer attorneys in general. See, e.g., Colson v. Reed, No. L-5294-97 (Sup. Ct. of N.J., Essex County), as well as the cases referred to supra. 54 See Barkley, 2007 WL 2437810. I have litigated similar cases in the Newark area. See, e.g., Gibson v. Bethea, No. L–5364–08 (N.J. Super. Ct. Law Div, Essex County Ct. 2008). 55 Barkley, 2007 WL 2437810 (denying motion to dismiss in property flipping case with claims against scammers under 42 U.S.C. §§ 198182, 1985(3)). 56 Id. at *11. 57 Id. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 139 and buyers of the same race.58 I have seen several such examples in my own litigation practice in Newark.59 Certain subprime lenders bypassed brokers and directly targeted their products to specific African-American and Hispanic divisions, euphemistically referred to as “Emerging Markets Departments.”60 Recent affidavits from former Wells Fargo employees submitted in the City of Baltimore v. Wells Fargo litigation, discussed infra, provide details.61 For instance, 58 Id. Other documented examples in reported cases include Hargraves v. Capital City Mortgage Corp., 140 F. Supp. 2d 7, 21–22 (D.D.C. 2000) (denying summary judgment where defendant mortgage company located its offices in predominantly black communities, used local brokers, distributed targeted flyers and ads in the same neighborhoods, and “exhibited photos of famous black leaders standing with the company’s president in an alleged ‘attempt to convey a message to African-Americans that [the president] could be trusted.’”); and Honorable v. Easy Life Real Estate Sys., Inc., 182 F.R.D. 553, 561 (N.D. Ill. Sept. 30, 1998) (certifying class in Fair Housing Act case and relying on allegations that “defendants preyed on the plaintiff class by targeting their advertising to unsophisticated, first-time home buyers in the racially segregated Austin community, materially misrepresenting the condition and value of homes offered for sale . . .”). 59 See Complaint, Gibson v. Bethea, No. L–5364–08 (N.J. Super. Ct. Law Div, Essex County Ct. 2008). 60 See, e.g., Business Wire, Option One Appoints Larry Gilmore Vice President of Emerging Markets, ALL BUS., April 7, 2006, http://www.all business.com/banking-finance/banking-lending-credit-services-mortgage/ 5466275-1.html. Minority homeownership rates are still a fraction of that of the general population, and shifting demographics and demographic growth among all minorities make understanding the needs of emerging markets more important now than ever . . . . “We’re developing a long-term strategy in Emerging Markets that will include the new type outreach and partnerships to provide the best quality services,” said Gilmore. “We will also look at developing unique products to meet the needs of our country’s diverse population.” Id. 61 See Affidavit of Elizabeth Jacobson, Mayor of Baltimore v. Wells Fargo Bank, N.A., No. 08-cv-00062 (D. Md. June 1, 2009) (opposing Wells Fargo’s motion to dismiss and submitted as Attachment M to Baltimore’s Amended Complaint); Affidavit of Tony Paschal, Wells Fargo, No. 08-cv- FISHER REVISED.DOC 140 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY the Emerging Markets manager informed one employee that she was “too white” to appear at a “wealth building” seminar in an African-American community and discuss “alternative lending,” the bank’s code for subprime lending.62 Another Wells employee, who worked in a division targeting zip codes with predominantly black populations, related that fellow employees referred to subprime loans as “ghetto loans.”63 Further, he explained that the bank had software to generate marketing materials for minorities, including a flyer “to persons speaking the language of ‘African-American.’”64 The lenders tailored their advertising and sales pitches to these populations, and operated out of branch offices in or near targeted neighborhoods.65 Some would blanket the neighborhoods with flyers featuring photos of black or Latino customers and public figures.66 Again, while targeting is not per se 00062 (opposing Wells Fargo’s motion to dismiss and submitted as Attachment N to the Amended Complaint); see also Complaint, People v. Wells Fargo & Co., No. 09CH26434 (Ill. Ch. Div., Cook County Ct. July 31,2009). 62 Jacobson Affidavit, supra note 61, at ¶ 29. 63 Pascal Affidavit, supra note 61, at ¶ 8. 64 Id. at ¶ 11. 65 See Ramirez v. Greenpoint Mortgage Funding, Inc., No. C080369, 2008 WL 2051018, at *1 (N.D. Cal. May 13, 2008) (noting lender branches were located in white neighborhoods, while broker outposts were located in minority neighborhoods, with brokers frequently charging more fees than lenders); Johnson v. Equicredit Corp. of Am., No. 01C5197, 2002 WL 448991, at *1 (N.D. Ill. March 22, 2002) (noting prime lender Bank of America located more often in white neighborhoods, while its subprime subsidiary Equicredit had offices almost exclusively located in minority neighborhoods). Two students of mine who were former employees of subprime lenders confirmed these lender tactics with me, as did Tamara Loatman-Clark, the attorney I have worked with who was interviewed by the American News Project. Interviews with Aaron Gould (Dec. 22, 2008); D.B. (July 15, 2007) and Tamara Loatman-Clark (May 4, 2009), Newark, New Jersey. 66 See Hargraves v. Capital City Mortgage Corp., 140 F. Supp. 2d 7, 2122 (D.D.C. 2000). A former student of mine described a situation in which acquaintances blanketed a minority neighborhood with racially targeted flyers at the behest of a local mortgage broker. See Interview with Aaron FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 141 discriminatory, it easily becomes so when the loans offered contain terms significantly worse than those offered to similarly situated white borrowers, which was the norm in the instances I recounted.67 II. CONSUMER FRAUD IN PREDATORY SUBPRIME LENDING The phenomenon of predatory subprime lending is by now well documented and has been defined and described in detail 68 elsewhere. Although no single definition of predatory lending exists, the phenomenon generally encompasses a variety of deceptive and unconscionable commercial practices that also constitute violations of unfair and deceptive acts and practices— or consumer fraud—statutes.69 In the mortgage lending context, these practices usually began with solicitations and aggressive, overbearing sales tactics employed against a financially unsophisticated target population. Typically, borrowers in foreclosure or those with low incomes but substantial equity in their homes would be solicited for refinances. For example, the Ninth Circuit upheld a jury verdict in a fraud class action against First Alliance Mortgage Company, which employed Gould, supra note 65. 67 See infra note 117 and accompanying text (describing the preliminary injunction obtained by the Massachusetts Attorney General in a reverse redlining suit against subprime lender Option One and H & R Block); see also Press Release, Fed. Trade Comm’n, Mortgage Lender Agrees to Settle FTC Charges that it Charged African-Americans and Hispanics Higher Prices for Loans (Dec. 16, 2008), available at http://www. ftc.gov. 68 See generally RICHARD BITNER, CONFESSIONS OF A SUBPRIME LENDER: AN INSIDER’S TALE OF GREED, FRAUD, AND IGNORANCE (2008) (detailing the rise and fall of the subprime lending market); Johnson, supra note 1, at 117880 (explaining predatory subprime loans); Frank Lopez, Using the Fair Housing Act to Combat Predatory Lending, 6 GEO. J. POVERTY L. & POL’Y 73, 76–80 (1999). 69 See generally CAROLYN CARTER & JONATHAN SHELDON, UNFAIR AND DECEPTIVE ACTS AND PRACTICES (Nat’l Consumer Law Ctr. 7th ed., 2008). A number of federal statutes, such as the Truth in Lending Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1601 et seq., may also apply. E.g., Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act (RESPA), 12 U.S.C. § 1201 et seq. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 142 scripted sales pitches to mislead mostly elderly borrowers about loan costs.70 The jury also found Lehman Brothers liable for aiding and abetting the fraud by financing the loans.71 Frequently, outright fraud was involved in the origination of predatory loans: brokers or loan officers falsified income and asset information on borrowers, and ordered inflated appraisals that overstated the value of the property.72 Over and over again in my litigation practice representing borrowers who unwisely trusted local brokers, I have seen mortgage applications filled out by brokers and loan officers—without borrower involvement—that contain wild exaggerations of the borrowers’ income and assets.73 As a result of this fraud, the homeowners 70 See, e.g., In re First Alliance Mortgage Co., 471 F.3d 977 (9th Cir. 2006) (upholding jury verdict in fraud class action against mortgage company that employed scripted sales pitch to mislead borrowers about loan costs; also upholding verdict against Lehman Bros., which financed the loans). Moreover, it should be noted that subprime borrowers were not unwittingly pulled into bad loans, and some seem to have overstated their income—rather than having a mortgage broker fill out their loan application. However, I have not seen evidence of that in my own practice representing borrowers in predatory lending litigation in New Jersey, although I do see evidence of broker fraud regularly. See Kareem Fahim, In New Jersey, Dreams of a Better Life Dashed by Foreclosure Crisis, N.Y. TIMES, May 19, 2009. 71 First Alliance, 471 F.3d at 989. 72 See, e.g., Road to Ruin: Mortgage Fraud Scandal Brewing, Huffington Post, May 13, 2009 available at http://www.huffingtonpost.com/ 2009/05/12/road-to-ruin-mortgage-fra_n_202016.html. Tamara LoatmanClark, a Brooklyn attorney and former employee of subprime lender Argent, is interviewed in this video about the fraudulent practices she observed at Argent; I am also interviewed. Id.; see also DENISE JAMES ET AL., MORTGAGE ASSET RESEARCH INST., ELEVENTH PERIODIC MORTGAGE FRAUD CASE REPORT TO: MORTGAGE BANKERS ASSOCIATION (2009) (reporting that incidents of mortgage fraud increased 26% between 2007 and 2008), available at http://www.marisolutions.com/pdfs/mba/mortgage-fraud-report11th.pdf. 73 This practice has been documented by the FBI and others. See, e.g., FED. BUREAU OF INVESTIGATION, 2008 MORTGAGE FRAUD REPORT “YEAR IN REVIEW” (2009) [hereinafter FBI 2008 REPORT], available at http://www.fbi.gov/publications/fraud/mortgage_fraud08.htm#3 (describing nature and incidence of current fraud schemes). This practice occurred in FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 143 were induced to take out mortgages with onerous terms that were unsuited to them and impossible to repay.74 Thus, after paying unconscionable closing costs,75 borrowers were saddled with mortgages whose principal balance exceeded fair market value and whose terms were not disclosed to them.76 During the peak subprime lending years of 2004 through 2006,77 so-called “exotic mortgages” with high adjustable rates setting in after a trial period, interest-only mortgages that were negatively amortizing, and similarly onerous loans were taken on by many borrowers who lacked a full understanding of the terms of their loan.78 Moreover, many subprime borrowers actually had credit scores sufficient to qualify for prime mortgages but were steered into subprime loans that were more profitable to lenders.79 Others took out refinance loans with high fees that rolled their unsecured credit card debt into secured debt.80 Indeed, some lenders promoted this practice as part of their lending strategy, and encouraged serial refinances because they made additional fees on each transaction.81 Deceptive sales pitches that almost every subprime lending case I have litigated in the last five years. 74 See Engel & McCoy, supra note 4 at 2043. 75 See MELISSA HUELSMAN, A BRIEF PRIMER ON PREDATORY LENDING PRACTICES (ABA General Practice Section Newsletter, Sept., 2005), available at http://www.abanet.org/genpractice/newsletter/lawtrends/0509/ business/predatorylending.html. 76 Over appraisals resulted in loans that were underwater from the beginning, because the homes were never worth as much as the inflated appraisal indicated. See generally BITNER, supra note 68 (discussing appraisal fraud). 77 See Edmund L. Andrews, Fed Shrugged as Subprime Crisis Spread, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 18, 2007. 78 Engel and McCoy, supra note 4, at 2076. 79 See supra note 7. 80 See LISA JAMES & JABRINA ROBERTS, CTR. FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, RISKING HOMES TO PAY OFF CREDIT CARDS 1–2 (2005), available at http://www.responsiblelending.org/credit-cards/research-analysis/ip012Risking_Homes_Credit_Cards-1105.pdf. 81 A former student of mine worked for HSBC’s subprime unit several years ago. Interview with Aaron Gould, HSBC, in Newark, N.J. (Dec. 16, 2008). He described how the bank would draw people into high-interest loans and solicit them again for mortgage refinancing after the original loans’ terms FISHER REVISED.DOC 144 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY misrepresented the terms and nature of these mortgage products were frequently used.82 Whether lenders relied on brokers or their own loan officers to originate loans, they often engaged in scant underwriting and made few efforts to verify the legitimacy of the applications and documentation presented to them.83 Because it was more profitable to flip the loans upstream than to fully confirm the information provided on loan applications, that step was bypassed and mortgages were quickly assigned to securitizers.84 Although these widespread practices occurred before the recent financial meltdown all but eradicated subprime lending, it should be noted that mortgage fraud, far from abating, has only 85 expanded since the foreclosure crisis began. The perpetrators became impossible to meet. Id. The strategy was to put borrowers into a position of increasing financial desperation, which would break down their resistance to taking out a new loan with unfavorable terms. Id. See also Daniel Wagner, Bank Employees Protest “Anti-Consumer” Practices, ABC NEWS, June 29, 2009, http://abcnews.go.com/Business/wireStory? id=7961452 (“Bank of America and other large banks encouraged customer service representatives and tellers to burden consumers with debt and enroll them in high-fee programs . . . .”). 82 Engel & McCoy, supra note 4, at 2088; see also supra text accompanying notes 49–57. 83 I have frequently seen loan applications containing obviously false information accepted and funded by subprime and Alt-A lenders. Stories of cases resulting in convictions around the country are reported daily by The Mortgage Fraud Reporter, Mortgage Fraud News, http://www.mortgage fraud.org/journal (last visited Aug. 27, 2009). See also Keys et al., supra note 4 (listing lax underwriting at origination as a cause of later default). 84 See Engel & McCoy, supra note 4, at 2039–43. 85 See, e.g., FBI 2008 REPORT, supra note 73 (describing nature and incidence of current mortgage fraud schemes); Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Treasury, Federal, State Partners Announce Multi-Agency Crackdown Targeting Foreclosure Rescue Scams, Loan Modification Fraud, Apr. 6, 2009, available at http://www/treas.gov/press/releases/tg83.htm (describing incidence of mortgage fraud). Recently, federal and state authorities have been prosecuting foreclosure rescue scammers both criminally and civilly as such schemes have proliferated, but I have been involved in litigating these cases for over ten years. In April of this year, the President also signed into law the Fraud Enforcement Recovery Act of 2009, which provides expanded enforcement powers to federal prosecutors in this area. See Fraud FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 145 adapt to the times and craft their pitches to address changing circumstances. In one variation—which began years ago but has become quite common recently—mortgage brokers work with foreclosure rescue scammers to target homeowners in foreclosure, offering to “temporarily” purchase their homes and rent them to the victims while they attempt to repair their credit. A straw purchaser takes title and finances the purchase with a mortgage arranged by the broker. The scammers then leave the former owners without title to the home, may evict the tenants and resell the property, use the sale to skim equity from the home and then let it fall into foreclosure, or otherwise profit from the transaction at the expense of the former homeowners.86 This pattern, as described in the New York case of Watson v. Melnikoff, is typical and has been replicated across the country.87 Another prevalent variation involves loan modification scams.88 In the wake of the widely-publicized efforts of Enforcement Recovery Act of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111–21, 123 Stat. 1617 (2009); see also Howard Goodman, The Fraud Squad, HUFFINGTON POST, June 22, 2009, www.huffingtonpost.com/2009/6/22/the-fraud-squad_n_ 218910.html (describing the Act and current efforts to attack new mortgage frauds in South Florida). 86 I have represented numerous clients victimized by similar scams, and the New Jersey Attorney General’s office is currently proceeding against a number of large foreclosure rescue rings. See, e.g., Press Release, N.J. Office of the Attorney General, Attorney General Announces Mortgage Fraud Lawsuits: 10 Defendants Charged in Two Separate Loan Modification Cases (July 15, 2009), available at http://www.nj.gov/oag/newsreleases09/pr2009 0715a.html. Similar stories from across the country are common. See also FBI REPORT, supra note 73 (describing the varieties of mortgage fraud). 87 Watson v. Melnikoff, 19 Misc. 3d 1130(A), (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 2008) (quieting title in favor of plaintiff and voiding fraudulent mortgage and title transfer). See also In Re Curriden, No. 05-38352, 2007 WL 2669431 (Bankr. D.N.J. Sept. 6, 2007). Another current problem for homeowners is that many subprime lenders failed to escrow for property taxes, leaving borrowers unaware that their taxes were not being paid. Many tax foreclosures have resulted. See Editorial, Another Way to Lose the House, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 27, 2009. 88 See Tara Siegel Bernard, Avoiding Firms that Prey on Troubled Homeowners, N.Y. TIMES, June 13, 2009; Peter S. Goodman, Subprime Brokers Back as Dubious Loan Fixers, N.Y. TIMES, July 20, 2009, available FISHER REVISED.DOC 146 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY government and nonprofit agencies to assist homeowners to modify their mortgages, a new generation of scammers has rushed in.89 Many are former mortgage brokers90 who falsely represent to borrowers that they must pay to obtain the services of a loan expert. In this way, the scammers demand substantial upfront fees.91 At best, these scammers do little more for borrowers than make a few phone calls, or engage in other efforts that borrowers could obtain elsewhere at no cost.92 At worst, they just take the money and run, leaving homeowners with false hopes and no avenue of redress.93 III. THE RACIALIZATION OF CONSUMER FRAUD & REVERSE REDLINING Predatory lending and consumer fraud occur when loan terms and fees cross the threshold of unconscionability, or when borrowers are enticed by deceptive sales practices and misrepresentations.94 Unsurprisingly, these practices have often been aimed at distinct segments of the population thought to be financially vulnerable—minorities, seniors, and sometimes single women.95 As recounted previously, black and Latino borrowers at http://www.nytimes.com/2009/07/20/business/20modify.html. 89 See Bernard, supra note 88. 90 See Goodman, supra note 88. 91 See Bernard, supra note 88. 92 See Goodman, supra note 88. 93 See Bernard, supra note 88. Yet another recent variation involves targeting senior citizens for reverse mortgages, by sending them officiallooking correspondence that appears to be from a government agency, cites various federal laws, and seems to offer government benefits. For example, a Sept. 4, 2009 letter from HECM Disbursement, Washington D.C., entitled Section 255 of the National Housing Act (12 U.S.C. 1715z-20) is amended: Notification of Eligibility: Identification Papers Issued to Received as Filed, is actually from the Eagle Nationwide Mortgage Company (on file with author). 94 See supra text accompanying notes 68–69. 95 See PEDATORY LENDING REPORT, supra note 1, at 4–5 (“[M]inorities, women, and the elderly bear the brunt of abusive mortgage lending practices, particularly in predominantly minority or low-income neighborhoods that do not have access to mainstream sources of credit.”). FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 147 in particular received a disproportionate share of the highest-cost subprime mortgages with less favorable terms than those made to similar white borrowers, even after controlling for risk-related factors.96 Targeted marketing of these mortgages amplified and intensified the worst lending practices by increasing both the pool of borrowers and their susceptibility to manipulative sales pitches. As set forth in many of the recent reverse redlining complaints surviving motions to dismiss, subprime lenders facilitated discriminatory lending by using discretionary pricing policies that encouraged mortgage brokers and loan officers working in minority neighborhoods to oversell.97 For instance, brokers received yield spread premiums, a form of commission, for placing borrowers into loans with higher interest rates than par, the rate for which the borrowers actually qualified.98 The 96 See BOCIAN ET AL., supra note 13, at 3; PREDATORY LENDING REPORT, supra note 1, at 3; see also Paul Jackson, NY AG: Mortgage Brokers Admit to Fee Gouging, Discrimination, HOUSINGWIRE, Jan. 6, 2009, http://www.housingwire.com/2009/01/06/ny-ag-firms-settle-predatory-lending -claims/ (reporting that as part of settlement with the New York Attorney General, brokers admitted charging higher fees to hundreds of black and Latino borrowers). 97 See Brescia, supra note 6 (analyzing discriminatory roots of the subprime crisis and viability of reverse redlining claims under the Fair Housing Act); John L. Ropiequet & L. Jean Noonan, Recent Developments in Fair Lending: The Dawn of a New Litigation Era?, 64 BUS. LAW. 563, 564 (2009); Stuart T. Rossman, The Foreclosure Crisis: Can Impact Litigation Provide a Response?, in 13TH ANNUAL CONSUMER FINANCIAL SERVICES LITIGATION INSTITUTE COURSE HANDBOOK, 195, 20204 (Practicing Law Inst. Ed., 2008); Christopher J. Willis & Catherine S. Bernard, Recent Subprime Mortgage Lending Class Actions Under the Equal Credit Opportunity Act and Fair Housing Act: An Analysis of Class Certification Issues, in 13TH ANNUAL CONSUMER FINANCIAL SERVICES LITIGATION INSTITUTE COURSE HANDBOOK, 163, 165 (Practicing Law Inst. Ed., 2008). Although the discretionary pricing policies were applicable to all borrowers, brokers and loan officers working in minority neighborhoods allegedly pushed local borrowers harder than white borrowers were pushed to take out high-cost loans that yielded higher commissions. See, e.g., Martinez v. Freedom Mortgage Team, Inc., 527 F. Supp. 2d 827, 835 (N.D. Ill. 2007). 98 Loan officers and brokers could be entitled to a percentage of the difference in revenue to the lender resulting from the higher rate loan. Ware FISHER REVISED.DOC 148 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY discretionary pricing policies also allowed brokers to profit from charging additional non-risk based fees99 to borrowers.100 Brokers were therefore incentivized to steer unwitting borrowers, including those with good credit who could have qualified for better terms, to the highest-cost loan products.101 Making matters worse, brokers—and some lenders— frequently targeted minority neighborhoods because they assumed residents would respond favorably to their pitches for these high-cost loan products.102 This is because borrowers with few financial options, or those unaware of other options, were more likely to take out higher-rate loans through subprime originators working in their neighborhoods.103 Moreover, brokered loans tend to cost more than direct loans—generating fees for brokers and lenders—and loans given in minority neighborhoods were more likely to be brokered than in white 104 neighborhoods. The lenders funding these loans allegedly v. Indymac Bank, 534 F. Supp. 2d 835, 839 (N.D. Ill. 2008). 99 See White, supra note 1. 100 Guerra v. GMAC LLC, No. 2:08–cv–01297, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 449153, at *4 (E.D. Pa. Feb. 20, 2009); Ramirez v. Greenpoint Mortgage Funding, No. C08-0369, 2008 WL 2051018, at *4–5 (N.D. Cal. May 13, 2008). 101 Commonwealth v. H&R Block, No. 2008-2474BLS1, 2008 Mass. Super. LEXIS 427, at *1 (Super. Ct. Nov. 25, 2008) (denying motion to dismiss and granting preliminary injunction); Complaint at ¶¶ 40–43, People v. Wells Fargo & Co., No. 09CH26434 (Ill. Ch. Div., Cook County Ct. July 31, 2009). 102 See Carol Necole Brown, Intent and Empirics: Race to the Subprime 27–42 (Univ. of N.C. Research Paper No. 1426142, 2009), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1426142 (relying on cultural affinity hypothesis, according to which lenders discriminate against borrowers with whom they do not share a cultural affinity because they have no context to evaluate creditworthiness, to explain racial targeting of subprime loans). 103 See supra note 6 and accompanying text. 104 Many of the complaints also include allegations that the defendant lenders worked with brokers more frequently in minority than in white neighborhoods, and knew that brokered loans were more expensive than direct loans. See, e.g., Ramirez, 2008 WL 2051018 at *1; see also White, supra note 1, at 687–88. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 149 knew of the disparate racial impact of their pricing policies.105 Compounding the problem, lenders failed to conduct serious underwriting, which encouraged originators to use inflated appraisals that overstated the market value of a home.106 The lack of underwriting also encouraged originators to falsify loan applications by inflating a borrower’s actual income and assets.107 Perhaps the greatest broker profits, however, came from commissions and fees earned from increased lending volume.108 Greater loan volume is precisely where careful targeting produced the greatest rewards. A number of the reverse redlining suits have been framed exclusively as civil rights violations, with liability theories premised upon violations of both the federal Fair Housing and Equal Credit Opportunity Acts, which prohibit, respectively, racially discriminatory actions affecting housing or the availability of credit.109 For instance, the plaintiffs in the 105 See, e.g., Ware v. Indymac Bank, 534 F. Supp. 2d 835, 840 (N.D. Ill. 2008); Martinez v. Freedom Mortgage Team, 527 F. Supp. 2d 827, 835 (N.D. Ill. 2007). 106 Ware, 534 F. Supp. 2d at 838–39; Barkley v. Olympia Mortgage Co., No. 04-CV-875, 2007 WL 2437810, at 1* (E.D.N.Y. Aug. 22, 2007). 107 Ware, 534 F. Supp. 2d at 838–39. 108 See ERNST ET AL., supra note 43, at 33 (“Brokers have strong incentives to originate mortgages in large volume and relatively little incentive to scrutinize whether the loans will perform over time.”). High sales volume was particularly important where subprime loans were bundled and sold into securitized pools, id., since the pools had to be filled within ninety days to comply with tax law. 109 For example, many of these cases involve claims under the Fair Housing Act, 42 U.S.C. § 3601 et seq., and the Equal Credit Opportunity Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1691 et seq. See Guerra v. GMAC LLC, No. 08-cv-01297, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 449153, at *1 (E.D. Pa. Feb. 20, 2009); Taylor v. Accredited Home Lenders, 580 F. Supp. 2d 1062, 1064 (S.D. Cal. 2008); Miller v. Countrywide Bank, N.A., 571 F. Supp. 2d 251, 253 (D. Mass. 2008); Ramirez, 2008 WL 2051018, at *2; Zamudio v. HSBC N. Am. Holdings, Inc., No. 07-c-4315, 2008 WL 517138, at *1 (N.D. Ill. Feb. 20, 2008); Jackson v. Novastar Mortgage, No. 06-2249, 2007 WL 4568976, at *1 (W.D. Tenn. Dec. 20, 2007). Some of the complaints also allege violations of 42 U.S.C. §§ 1981–82. See John Relman, Foreclosures, Integration, and the Future of the Fair Housing Act, 41 IND. L. REV. 629 FISHER REVISED.DOC 150 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY representative disparate impact case of Miller v. Countrywide Bank, N.A alleged that: Countrywide’s Discretionary Pricing Policy has a widespread discriminatory impact on African-American applicants for home mortgage loans, in violation of the Equal Credit Opportunity Act [citation omitted] and Fair Housing Act [citation omitted]. That system . . . makes African-Americans over three times more likely than white borrowers to receive a high-APR [annual percentage rate] home loan and two times more likely to receive a high-APR refinancing loan. The disparity . . . is not fully explained by any objective indicia of creditworthiness, such as credit history, credit score, debt-to-income ratio, or loan-to-value ratio. Instead, they argue that a significant portion of the disparity is explained by Countrywide’s pricing policy, which explicitly allows for subjective price markups . . . . These . . . have a disparate impact on African-American home buyers.110 According to the court, these allegations sufficed to withstand a motion to dismiss because the plaintiffs had sufficiently pled that a specified policy was the proximate cause of the racially disproportionate effects they challenged.111 The evidence in certain reverse redlining cases includes practices that would constitute consumer fraud as well.112 The City of Baltimore provided evidence that Wells Fargo employees steered borrowers qualifying for prime loans to more costly subprime loans by misleadingly telling minority applicants that only subprime loans could be processed quickly and that mandatory prepayment penalties could be waived, but not 113 informing them about the higher cost of subprime loans. State (2008) (placing the Baltimore Wells Fargo litigation in broader legal context). 110 Miller, 571 F. Supp. 2d at 253 (internal citations omitted). 111 Id. at 255–58. 112 See supra text accompanying notes 72–84. 113 Jacobson Affidavit, supra note 61, at ¶¶ 12. Similar tactics apparently extended to Wells Fargo’s efforts to hire loan officers. Several years ago, I interviewed a former Wells Fargo subprime division employee who explained FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 151 statutes typically prohibit the use of false and deceptive sales tactics such as these. For instance, the New Jersey Consumer Fraud Act prohibits the “act, use or employment . . . of any unconscionable commercial practice, deception, fraud, false pretense, false promise, misrepresentation, or the knowing concealment, suppression or omission, in connection with the sale or advertisement of any merchandise or real estate.”114 These practices were perpetrated disproportionately upon African-American and Latino borrowers, and cannot be justified on neutral business necessity grounds because white borrowers with similar credit scores and other risk characteristics received better loans than the inferior, high-cost products foisted on minority borrowers. Thus, the acts alleged could constitute race discrimination, as well as consumer fraud.115 Some reverse redlining suits, however, have asserted both civil rights and consumer fraud violations.116 A prominent example is State of Massachusetts v. H & R Block, et al., in which a state court denied a motion to dismiss and issued a preliminary injunction requiring Attorney General approval before proceeding with foreclosures on presumptively unfair that the bank sought to hire loan officers by claiming it was providing valuable credit opportunities to new and previously neglected pools of borrowers, though these borrowers were actually taken advantage of and given inferior products. Interview with P.T., in Montclair, N.J., (Feb. 2006). 114 N.J. STAT. Ann. §56:8–2 (2009). 115 See Lambert, supra note 15, at 220314 (analyzing the applicability of both disparate treatment and disparate impact theories to claims of discriminatory credit marketing). See also Aleo & Svirsky, supra note 1; Peter E. Mahoney, The End(s) of Disparate Impact: Doctrinal Reconstruction, Fair Housing and Lending Law, and the Antidiscrimination Principle, 47 EMORY L.J. 409 (1998). 116 See, e.g., Ware v. Indymac Bank, 534 F. Supp. 2d 835, 838 (N.D. Ill. 2008); Newman v. Apex Fin. Group, Inc., No. 07 C 4475, 2008 WL 130924, at *1 (N.D. Ill. Jan. 11, 2008); Martinez v. Freedom Mortgage Team, Inc., 527 F. Supp. 2d 827, 834–35 (N.D. Ill. 2007); Johnson v. Equicredit Corp. of Am., No. 01 C 5197, 2002 WL 448991, at *1 (N.D. Ill. Mar. 22, 2002); Assocs. Home Equity Servs. v. Troup, 343 N.J. Super. 254, 262 (App. Div. 2001). FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 152 categories of mortgage loans.117 The complaint alleged not only that the defendants engaged in unfair lending practices, but also that targeting was used to steer minority borrowers to inferior mortgages: [The defendants] produced and distributed to its [sic] employees, loan officers, and brokers written marketing and educational materials explaining that the limited choices available to black and Latino borrowers made them good candidates for the [defendants’] subprime loan products and that loan originators should focus on the “emerging markets” of black and Latino homebuyers . . . [The defendants] described this “emerging market” as potential buyers who may have credit concerns, a lack of familiarity with the credit system, and difficulty demonstrating conventional credit history.118 The combination of both anti-discrimination and consumer fraud claims better captures the reality of targeted predatory lending. Existing anti-discrimination and consumer fraud statutes are sufficiently broad to encompass these targeting practices, and the lawsuits I have described have the potential to shape the law to effectively address those practices. The level of enforcement efforts, however, has not kept pace with the severity of the problem.119 The next section addresses recent legislation and proposals that have the potential to increase both the efficacy and level of enforcement efforts. IV. FEDERAL RESPONSES TO REVERSE REDLINING The use of target marketing to funnel mortgages with disadvantageous terms to residents of minority neighborhoods warrants further attention from regulators as well as courts. 117 Commonwealth v. H&R Block, Inc., No. 2008-2474BLS1, 2008 Mass. Super. LEXIS 427, at *92 (Super. Ct. Nov. 25, 2008). 118 Complaint at ¶¶ 120, 121, Commonwealth v. H&R Block, Inc., No. 2008-2474BLS1, 2008 Mass. Super. LEXIS 427 (Super. Ct. June 3, 2008). 119 See, e.g., Andrews, supra note 77. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 153 While sellers have identified potential buyers based on their susceptibility to fine-tuned sales practices for centuries, today’s highly refined marketing technologies have increased the efficiency of sharp selling practices and functioned as tools for discrimination.120 Unfortunately, the profit-making frenzy that developed during the peak subprime lending years caused not only low-level scammers to prey on black and Latino borrowers, but also drew larger lenders and banks into the picture. The need for increased enforcement of existing law is self-evident, but new regulation that focuses particularly on the practices addressed in this article could prevent future problems while remedying past ones. The federal government has recently taken steps to ensure greater regulation of mortgage brokers through the Secure and Fair Enforcement for Mortgage Licensing Act (the S.A.F.E. Act). Part of the Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008, the S.A.F.E. Act establishes uniform licensing and registration requirements for “loan originators.”121 While reasonable licensing requirements will likely help prevent some of the worst originator abuses of the peak subprime lending years, more is needed. Legislators and regulators also need to address the role of lenders in pushing overly complex and predatory loans on unsuspecting borrowers and ignoring standard underwriting requirements in their rush to profit from assigning the mortgages into securitized trusts. The proposed Consumer Financial Protection Agency (CFPA) could provide additional protections for borrowers.122 120 See Lambert, supra note 15, at 2203–14. Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-289, § 1502(1), 122 Stat. 2850 (2008). This legislation provides a regulatory floor for states, and specifies that HUD will establish a system for noncompliant states; see also Bob Tedeschi, Cracking Down on Certain Brokers, N.Y. TIMES, June 7, 2009, at RE6 (“[T]he F.H.A. is tightening its review of mortgage professionals who are permitted to originate its loans.”); Bob Tedeschi, Monitoring Loan Officers, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 23, 2009, at RE9. 122 Consumer Financial Protection Agency Act of 2009, H.R. 3126, 111th Cong. (2009). In June of 2009, the Obama administration proposed a single agency to regulate consumer financial products. See Mike Allen & Eamon Javers, Barack Obama to Create Consumer Financial Protection 121 FISHER REVISED.DOC 154 4/26/2010 11:40 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY For the first time, the CFPA would consolidate regulation of all consumer financial products—including mortgages—under the aegis of a single agency whose sole mission and priority would be to safeguard the rights of consumers.123 This agency’s mandate would be to “promote transparency, simplicity, fairness, accountability and access in the market for consumer financial products or services.”124 It would have authority, inter alia, to prohibit unfair and deceptive practices in the financial Agency, POLITICO, June 17, 2009, http://www.politico.com/news/stories/ 0609/23790.html; see also Regulatory Restructuring: Enhancing Consumer Financial Products Regulation: Hearing on H.R. 3126 Before the H. Financial Servs. Comm., 111th Cong. (2009). Elizabeth Warren, Leo Gottlieb Professor of Law, Harvard University, has made public statements supporting administration proposal for new Consumer Financial Protection Agency: If we don’t feed high-risk, high-profit loans into the system, those risks will not get sliced and diced into questionable asset-backed securities and sold throughout the financial system. If we had a Consumer Financial Protection Agency five years ago, Liar’s Loans and no-doc loans would never have made it into the financial marketplace—and never would have brought down our banking system. The economic system took on so much risk—one household at a time—that it destabilized our entire economy. Id. 123 See U.S. DEP’T OF THE TREASURY, FINANCIAL REGULATORY REFORM, A NEW FOUNDATION 55–70 (2009), available at http://www.financialstability.gov/docs/regs/FinalReport_web.pdf [hereinafter TREASURY REPORT]; see also Binyamin Appelbaum, As Subprime Lending Crisis Unfolded, Watchdog Fed Didn’t Bother Barking, WASH. POST, Sept. 27, 2009 (reporting that the Federal Reserve, which has enforcement authority in this area, ignored evidence of subprime lending a abuses for years); Edmund L. Andrews, Banks Balk at Agency Meant to Aid Consumers, N.Y. TIMES, June 30, 2009, at B1; Press Release, Ctr. for Responsible Lending, Top Policies for Addressing the Foreclosure Crisis (Aug. 2009), available at http://www.responsiblelending.org/mortgage-lending/policylegislation/congress/mortgage-solutions-final.pdf (informing readers that while other agencies have made consumer protection a low priority, this new agency would have the single mission of protecting consumers from financial abuses in mortgages, credit cards, bank overdraft fees, and other financial products). 124 H.R. 3126 § 121. FISHER REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:40 PM TARGET MARKETING OF SUBPRIME LOANS 155 products market.125 Moreover, the CFPA would restrict the ability of originators—whether brokers or subprime lenders—to mislead borrowers with inordinately complex financial products.126 Finally—and most critical to this article—the agency would have the authority to curb reverse redlining and the racialization of consumer fraud by enforcing the Equal Credit Opportunity Act and the Community Reinvestment Act.127 Bringing enforcement of antidiscrimination law under the same umbrella as enforcement of other consumer protection law should amplify the power of each to eradicate the array of illegal practices that enabled the current crisis. The complexities of the problem demand that each issue not be addressed in isolation. 125 Id. at §§ 131–39. The Obama administration recently withdrew its original proposal to give the new agency the power to require lenders to offer “plain-vanilla” mortgages, with simpler and more straightforward pricing. See TREASURY REPORT, supra note 123, at 66; Damian Paletta and Kara Scannell, Democrats Soften Financial Bill, WALL ST. J., Sept. 24, 2009. 126 TREASURY REPORT, supra note 123, at 66. 127 Id. at 58–59, 69–70. SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS AND COMPREHENSIVE PLANNING: BALANCING COMMUNITY EMPOWERMENT AND THE POLICE POWER Patricia E. Salkin and Amy Lavine* I. INTRODUCTION Traditionally, the states have empowered local governments to develop plans and implement regulations for neighborhood and community development. When accomplished at the local or regional level, the interests and benefits of the community as a whole are to be weighed against the detriments to individuals. Much has been studied and written about the lack of meaningful public participation in the planning and land use regulatory process, suggesting that often low-income and minority communities are not fully engaged in the process, even when it may result in decisions negatively impacting their 1 neighborhoods. Case studies have also shown that governments * Patricia E. Salkin is the Associate Dean, Director of the Government Law Center and the Raymond & Ella Smith Distinguished Professor of Law at Albany Law School. Amy Lavine is a staff attorney at the Government Law Center and the author of the Community Benefits Blog http://communitybenefits.blogspot.com. 1 See, e.g., Sheila Foster, Justice from the Ground Up: Distributive Inequities, Grassroots Resistance, and the Transformative Politics of the Environmental Justice Movement, 86 CAL. L. REV. 775, 831–837 (1998); Alejandro Esteban Camacho, Mustering the Missing Voices: A Collaborative Model for Fostering Equality, Community Involvement and Adaptive Planning in Land Use Decisions Installment One, 24 STAN. ENVTL. L.J. 3, 15–36 (2005) [hereinafter Camacho I]. It should also be noted that planning and 157 SALKIN REVISED.DOC 158 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY are sometimes so eager to stimulate local economic development that they fail to fully engage communities in the project review process, both to expedite development and to avoid confronting local opposition.2 This emphasis on short-term economic growth, however, may obscure a local government’s perception of the social and environmental needs of particular communities. When this occurs, formal planning processes have failed to accomplish their goals of engaging community members and guiding future growth in a manner that maximizes long-term benefits for the common good. zoning boards tend to be composed of community elites, who often have ties to the development sector. AMERICAN PLANNING ASSOCIATION, GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK: MODEL STATUTES FOR PLANNING AND THE MANAGEMENT OF CHANGE 7–13 (2002) [hereinafter, GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK]. See generally, Jerry L. Anderson, Is the Wheel Unbalanced? A Study of Bias on Zoning Boards, 36 URB. LAW. 447 (2004) (arguing that bias pervades zoning boards in favor of entrenched interests). The lack of socioeconomic diversity is particularly acute in larger cities, which results in “a pronounced bias toward the professional/technical/managerial class in our cities.” Id. at 464; see also Jerry L. Anderson, A Study of American Zoning Board Composition and Public Attitudes Toward Zoning Issues (Apr. 2008), http://papers.ssrn.com/ sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1119582. But see Wayne Senville, Survey of Planning Board Members Enlightening (Oct. 2002), http://www.planetizen. com/node/66 (suggesting, in a less scientific survey, that greater diversity is being achieved on planning board). 2 For example, plans for the Melrose Commons redevelopment project in the South Bronx were initially formed without community involvement, and they were poorly coordinated with the community’s needs. Changes were made only after residents organized and presented their concerns to planning officials. Eventually, the community’s initiative led to substantial modifications, and the project is today viewed as a success. See SUSTAINABLE COMMUNITIES NETWORK CASE STUDIES, URBAN RENEWAL in MELROSE COMMONS, (Sept. 18, 1996), http://www.sustainable.org/casestudies/ newyork/NY_af_melrose.html; see also Amy Wideman, Replacing Politics with Democracy: A Proposal for Community Planning in New York City and Beyond, 11 J.L. & POL’Y 135, 197 (2002) (describing New York City’s response to a community-based plan as “focus[ing] inordinately on economic repercussions for the city and what the city’s role and expenses would be in implementing aspects of the plan that could inhibit future industrial sitings in the neighborhood”). SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 159 New approaches to planning provide one response to systemic public participation problems. The environmental justice movement, for example, has sought to ensure a fair distribution of both environmental burdens and environmental goods by requiring local governments to make meaningful public participation available to all community members. Communitybased planning efforts have attempted to improve the planning process by focusing on small and distinct geographic areas and by developing collaborative and inclusive planning programs. Since the late 1990s, community benefits agreements (CBAs) have offered another method to increase community input in the development planning and review process. CBAs, in their purest form, are private contracts between a developer and a coalition of community interest groups.3 For communities that have historically been excluded from the planning process, CBAs can be a powerful tool to ensure that neighborhood interests are addressed as an integral component of development.4 By using CBAs, community coalitions can make project sponsors respond to their needs and interests, and they can bind developers to their promises through legally enforceable contract terms. Perhaps more significantly, the community is empowered to speak and make decisions for itself on myriad issues, including negotiating for community amenities that have traditionally been within the purview of the local comprehensive planning regime. The result, ideally, is growth 3 See Julian Gross, Community Benefits Agreements: Definitions, Values, and Legal Enforceability, 17 J. AFFORDABLE HOUSING & COMMUNITY DEV. L. 35, 46 (2008). 4 See, e.g., Ryan Juskus & Elizabeth Elia, Long Time Coming, 150 SHELTERFORCE ONLINE (2007), available at http://www.nhi.org/online/ issues/150/longtimecoming.html (“A neighborhood famous for its vitality under the constraints of segregation, Shaw was neglected and abused for so many ensuing decades . . . . One DC and Shaw resident claimed these blighted lots as community assets and declared that even these properties, if jealously guarded, could be a source of neighborhood power and wealth. This is the revolutionary idea of community-benefits agreements: that the community members—even those without money or power, who are usually ignored in development plans or manipulated like chess pieces—can be an asset and a force with which to contend.”). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 160 and development that is accountable to the people it affects and equitable in its distribution of benefits and burdens. However, the people it affects are often a small subset of the municipal jurisdiction and the equitable distribution sought in the CBAs is limited to the proposed project area. The legal relationship between CBAs and planning is unclear. Critics may perceive CBAs as circumventing government planning processes in order to put insular neighborhood concerns ahead of broader metropolitan interests.5 Supporters, on the other hand, may view traditional planning processes as inadequate and may see CBAs as a tool to advance civic engagement.6 CBA coalitions have been accused of abusing the tool when they fail to represent the full spectrum of community stakeholders, but as yet no workable definition of the “community” has been established.7 This article explores how the comprehensive planning process and CBAs complement and contradict each other, and how both could be improved by innovative and more inclusive planning techniques. Part II provides a brief historical background on comprehensive planning and community development, including issues relating to community planning and public participation. Part III examines CBAs and their role in community empowerment, community development and the promotion of social justice principles, including equitable development. This part also provides examples of typical land use related elements found in existing CBAs. Using these examples, Part IV segues into a discussion regarding whether private CBAs usurp the public planning process. The section explores whether CBAs are just another type of communitybased plan and whether CBAs advance narrow interests at the expense of the larger community. The question of what local governments should do when presented with a CBA that is inconsistent with the local comprehensive land use plan is examined to determine whether amending the plan to incorporate 5 6 7 See infra Part IV.B. Gross, supra note 3, at 38. See infra Part III.A.1. SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 161 the community vision as articulated through the CBA is appropriate. The article concludes in Part V by pointing out that shortcomings of the current regulatory system allow local governments, intentionally or inadvertently, to exclude robust public participation from the development and implementation of comprehensive land use plans. This provides the impetus for privately negotiated CBAs, but these agreements may not always be ideal because not all parties to a CBA will have the best interests of the neighborhood or the community as a whole at the forefront of their agendas. While many CBAs have been successful, a number of case studies also reveal pitfalls in the process. The article concludes with the belief that local governments must be more inclusive and accountable in the public planning process to better meet the true goals of the community benefits movement. II. COMPREHENSIVE PLANNING AND COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT A. The Origins of Traditional Comprehensive Planning The federal and state governments have long recognized the role of municipalities in comprehensive planning for community development.8 Planning, in this context, may be best described as “an attempt to coordinate the development of all the interrelated aspects of the physical environment, and all the closely related aspects of the social and economic environment.”9 At the First National Conference on City Planning and the Problems of Congestion, which was convened in Washington, D.C., in 1909, Frederick Law Olmstead, Jr., described city plans as “a compendium of all regulations on building, physical development, ‘districting’ of land, health ordinances, and ‘police rules’ for the use and development of 8 See generally SALKIN, AMERICAN LAW OF ZONING §§ 5:2, 5:11 (5th ed. 2009) [hereinafter SALKIN, AMERICAN LAW OF ZONING]. 9 NORMAN WILLIAMS, JR. & JOHN M. TAYLOR, AMERICAN LAND PLANNING LAW, VOL. 1 10 (Thomson West 2003). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 162 land.”10 Almost 20 years later, Alfred Bettman described the city plan as: . . . a master design for the physical development of the territory of the city. It constitutes the division of land between public and private uses, specifying the general location and extent of new public improvements, grounds and structures . . . and, in the case of private developments, the general distribution [of land areas] amongst various classes of uses, such as residential, business and industrial uses.11 Beginning with the Model Standard City Planning Enabling Act in 1928 (“Standard Act”), local governments were vested with authority to develop community-wide plans.12 The Act provided for the establishment of a planning commission, which would be vested with the responsibility “to make and adopt a master plan for the physical development of the municipality . . . including, among other things, the general location, character, and extent of streets, viaducts, subways, bridges, waterways, water fronts, boulevards, parkways, playgrounds, squares, parks, aviation fields, and other public ways . . . .”13 The Standard Act additionally included provisions for the adoption of a master street plan, provisions for the approval of all public improvements by the planning commission, subdivision controls, and provisions for the establishment of a regional planning commission and a regional plan.14 Under the model set forth in the Standard Act, non10 JULIAN CONRAD JUERGENSMEYER & THOMAS E. ROBERTS, LAND USE PLANNING AND CONTROL LAW 21 (West Group, 1998). 11 Id. at 22 (citing PLANNING PROBLEMS OF TOWN, CITY AND REGION: PAPERS AND DISCUSSIONS OF THE TWENTIETH NATIONAL CONFERENCE ON CITY PLANNING, reprinted in W. GOODMAN & E. FREUND, PRINCIPLES AND PRACTICE OF URBAN PLANNING, 352–53 (4th ed. 1968)). 12 U.S. Department of Commerce, A Standard City Planning Enabling Act (1928), available at http://myapa.planning.org/growingsmart/pdf/CP EnablingAct1928.pdf. 13 Id. at 13–15. 14 Id.; see also, Ruth Knack et al., The Real Story Behind the Standard Planning and Zoning Acts of the 1920s, Feb. 1996, at 4–6, available at SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 163 elected officials dominated the local planning function.15 It was believed that their arguably non-partisan status made them better suited than elected politicians to take a hard look at challenging planning issues.16 Most of the states adopted the Standard Act, and although many of the states’ comprehensive planning statutes have been modernized, the influence of the Standard Act continues to resonate today.17 A process-oriented statute, one of the Standard Act’s most significant influences was its preference for optional rather than mandatory planning.18 While this led to the belief that planning was not necessarily a prerequisite to the adoption of zoning laws, Alfred Bettman explained that “[t]he zoning ordinance is, of course, execution and the planning precedes it . . . .”19 Today, a comprehensive land use plan20 commonly refers to a written document that is formally adopted by a local legislative body, which contains goals, objectives and strategies for the future development and conservation of the community.21 It http://myapa.planning.org/growingsmart/pdf/LULZDFeb96.pdf. 15 GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at 7–11. 16 Id. 17 See Rodney L. Cobb, Toward Modern Statutes: A Survey of State Laws on Local Land-Use Planning, in MODERNIZING STATE PLANNING STATUTES: THE GROWING SMART WORKING PAPERS 21 (1998). 18 DANIEL R. MANDELKER, LAND USE LAW §3.05 (5th ed., LexisNexis Matthew Bender 2003). 19 Charles M. Harr, The Master Plan: An Impermanent Constitution, 20 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 353, 362 (1955) (quoting an unpublished note written by Bettman). 20 Depending upon local definition, the terms “comprehensive land use plan,” “master plan” and “general plan” may be used interchangeably. 21 However, while either legally or intuitively the comprehensive plan should be a written document, this is not the case in all states. For example, in New York, the enabling statutes suggest that a comprehensive plan be a written document. N.Y. Town Law § 272–a. (2009). However, the statutes also recognize the validity of prior caselaw that allowed the concept of the comprehensive plan to be a reflection of an ongoing planning process rather than “pay slavish servitude to any particular document.” Udell v. Haas, 235 N.E.2d 897, 902 (1968). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 164 should represent the “big picture” of what the community looks like today and what it aspires to look like in the future,22 and the policies identified in the plan should guide development regulations and decisions made under them.23 By providing a baseline for consistency regarding local governments’ land use decisions, the comprehensive plan helps to safeguard against arbitrary, irrational, biased and ad hoc actions.24 Most states do not make the adoption of a comprehensive plan a statutory pre-requisite to the adoption of zoning regulations,25 but the notion that the plan precedes the regulation is widely accepted as a best practice.26 Where there is a comprehensive plan, the states also diverge on the question of whether zoning must be consistent with it: some states give no significance to the plan and do not require consistency; the majority of states do not require consistency but do consider the plan to be a factor in the evaluation of zoning regulations; and the rest hold the plan to be controlling and require all land use actions to be consistent with its goals and policies.27 Long a 22 See GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at 7-6. JOHN R. NOLON, WELL GROUNDED: PRIMER FOR LOCAL OFFICIALS AND CITIZENS 18 (1998); GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at 7-7. 24 See GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at 7-7; Daniel J. Curtin & Jonathan D. Witten, Windfalls, Wipeouts, Givings, and Takings in Dramatic Redevelopment Projects: Bargaining for Better Zoning on Density, Views, and Public Access, 32 B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 325, 335 (2005) (discussing the importance of a comprehensive plan in preventing manipulation of the planning process for private gain). 25 See Stuart Meck, The Legislative Requirement that Zoning and Land Use Controls Be Consistent with an Independently Adopted Local Comprehensive Plan: A Model Statute, 3 WASH. U. J.L. & POL’Y 295, 305 (2000) [hereinafter Meck, A Model Statute]. A survey published by the American Planning Association in 1998 revealed that ten states made local planning optional, twenty-five states made it conditionally mandatory (i.e., local governments would only be required to develop a plan if they created a planning commission); and fifteen states made local planning mandatory. Cobb, supra note 17, at 21–23. 26 See SALKIN, AMERICAN LAW OF ZONING, supra note 8 at § 5:1. 27 Edward J. Sullivan, Recent Developments in Comprehensive Planning Law, 40 URB. LAW. 549, 549 (2008). The three approaches are referred to as 23 SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 165 minority position, the consistency approach has steadily been gaining ground, with the result that “the comprehensive plan has been invested with an increasing role in judging land use regulations or actions so that . . . plans are required and, once in place, are a significant, if not decisive, factor . . . .”28 The general goals and policies enunciated in modern comprehensive plans are typically organized into separate elements covering such issues as land use, housing, transportation, public facilities, open space, and economic development.29 The American Planning Association’s Growing Smart Legislative Guidebook, which was intended to provide a modern update of the Standard Act,30 recommends that state planning enabling statutes reflect a three tiered approach to local comprehensive plan elements: the most important elements, such as housing and transportation, should be mandatory; important elements that may not be appropriate for smaller local governments, or for other good reasons, should have an opt-out alternative; and elements that are not essential, but which the state considers appropriate planning topics, should be optional.31 The states have taken varying approaches. For example, Florida’s enabling statute is very detailed and includes mandatory, opt-out and optional elements.32 In New York, by the “unitary view” (plans not required and given no effect), the “planning factor view” (plans are a factor in judging land use regulations), and the “planning mandate view” (plans required and zoning must be consistent with them). Id.; see also Curtin & Witten, supra note 24, at 331–37 (2005) (discussing different state approaches to comprehensive planning). 28 Sullivan, supra note 27, at 549. 29 See GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at 7-61 to 7-66. 30 Recognizing that “[t]he planning approaches of the 1920s are incapable of meeting the challenges of the twenty-first century[,]” the American Planning Association decided to develop a new set of model guidelines. The product culminated in the Growing Smart Legislative Guidebook, which contains model planning statutes and commentary to help explain their purposes and applications. GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at xxix–xxx. 31 Id. at 7-62. 32 FLA. STAT. § 163.3177 (2009). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 166 contrast, the state has chosen to provide statutory guidance as to the appropriate elements to be addressed in the comprehensive plan, but the listing of elements is completely optional.33 Other states fall somewhere in the middle. Arizona specifies both mandatory and optional elements, which may vary depending on the city’s size,34 and while Idaho’s statute is limited to mandatory elements, it allows local governments to opt out if they can explain why they should not have to address a particular element.35 The elements specified in Maryland’s planning legislation are almost all mandatory, with only one optional topic,36 whereas New Hampshire requires only two sections but provides a list of more than a dozen optional elements.37 An important characteristic of the comprehensive planning framework is that plans remain flexible and open to change, allowing the creation of new planning goals and new strategies to achieve existing ones. The Growing Smart Guidebook, recognizing that plans must be continually reassessed in light of changing physical assets and new social paradigms, recommends that local governments review and revise their plans at least once every five years.38 The statutory content of comprehensive plans has similarly expanded over the years. Contemporary elements have focused on such issues as affordable housing,39 alternative transportation,40 mixed-use development,41 33 N.Y. TOWN LAW § 272–a (2003). ARIZ. REV. STAT. ANN. § 9–461.05 (2009). 35 IDAHO CODE ANN. § 67–6508 (2007). 36 MD. ANN. CODE art. 66B, § 1.04 (2009). 37 N.H. REV. STAT. ANN. § 674:2 (2008). 38 See GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at 7-230 to 7-233. 39 See, e.g., CAL. GOV’T CODE § 65583(c)(1)(B)(4) (Deering 2009); NEV. REV. STAT. ANN. § 278.160(1)(e)(2) (West 2009). 40 See, e.g., ARIZ. REV. STAT. ANN. 9–461.05(E)(9); FLA. STAT. § 163.3177(3)(a)(6) (amended 2008); MD. CODE ANN., Art. 66B, § 3.05(a)(4)(iii)(2) (2009); NEV. REV. STAT. ANN. § 278.160(1)(q) (2009); OR. ADMIN. R. 660-012-0020(2); S.C. CODE ANN. § 6-29-510(D)(8) (amended 2007); WASH. REV. CODE § 36.70A.070(6)(a)(vii) (2005); WIS. 34 SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 167 environmental protection,42 disaster management,43 and water resources.44 Community awareness regarding the impacts of human development on climate change has recently prompted some states to amend their planning statutes to include alternative energy and sustainability goals.45 Local governments, even where not required, have frequently adopted similar elements in their general plans.46 STAT. § 66.1001(2)(c) (2009). 41 See, e.g., ARIZ. REV. STAT. § 11–821(C)(1)(b) (amended 2008); CONN. GEN. STAT. ANN. § 8-23(c), (d)(1) (2009); FLA. STAT. § 163.3177(6)(a) (2009); NEV. REV. STAT. ANN. § 278.160(1)(f) (2009). 42 See, e.g., ARIZ. REV. STAT. §§ 11–821(D)(2), 9–461.05(E)(1) (amended 2008); CAL. GOV. CODE § 65302(d); N.H. REV. CODE ANN. § 674:2(III)(d) (2009); MD. CODE ANN. art. 66B, § 3.05(a)(4)(ix) (amended 2009); MASS. GEN. LAWS ch. 41, § 81D(5) (amended 1998); N.H. REV. STAT. ANN. § 674:2(III)(d). (2009); NEV. REV. STAT. ANN. § 278.160(1)(b) (2009); 53 PENN. STAT. ANN. § 10301(a)(6) (2000); S.C. CODE ANN. § 6– 29–510(D)(4) (amended 2005); WIS. STAT. § 66.1001(2)(e) (2009). 43 See, e.g., CAL. GOV. CODE § 65302(g)(2009); FLA. STAT. § 163.3177(7)(h) (2009); N.H. REV. STAT. ANN. § 674:2(III)(e) (2009); NEV. REV. STAT. ANN. § 278.160(1)(l). 44 See, e.g., ARIZ. REV. STAT. §§ 9–461.05(D)(5), 11–821(C)(3) (amended 2008); COLO. REV. STAT.§ 30–28–106 sec. (3) (IV) (amended 2009); FLA. STAT. § 163.3177(6)(c)(2009); MD. CODE ANN. Art. 66B, § 3.05(a)(4)(vi) (amended 2009); 53 PENN. STAT. ANN. § 10301(b) (2000). 45 In 2008, for example, Florida amended its planning enabling act to require local plans to consider methods to discourage urban sprawl, support energy-efficient development patterns, and reduce greenhouse gases. See Act of July 1, 2008, 2008 Fla. Laws ch. 191 (codified as amended at FLA. STAT. § 163.3177). Arizona also requires planning for energy efficiency and renewable energy development. ARIZ. REV. STAT. §§ 11-821 (C)(4), 9461.05 (E) (10); see also N.J. STAT. § 40:55D-28 (b)(16) (West 2009); COLO. REV. STAT. §§ 30-28-106 (3)(a)(VI), 31-23-206 (1)(f); 53 PENN. STAT. ANN. § 10301.1 (2009). 46 Patricia E. Salkin, Sustainability and Land Use Planning: Greening State and Local Land Use Plans and Regulations to Address Climate Change Challenges and Preserve Resources for Future Generations, 34 WM. & MARY ENVTL. L. & POL’Y REV. 121 (2009). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 168 B. Community-Based Planning Despite a lack of guidance from most state comprehensive planning statutes,47 “[t]here has long been a move away from centralized planning in the urban context toward more community-based planning.”48 Strongly influenced by the racial and socioeconomic discrimination endemic in the implementation of urban renewal plans, and the Civil Rights movement of the 1960s, Paul Davidoff articulated a theory of “advocacy planning” in 1965 that remains applicable today: The recommendation that city planners represent and plead the plans of many interest groups is founded upon the need to establish an effective urban democracy, one in which citizens may be able to play an active role in the process of deciding public policy. Appropriate policy in a democracy is determined through a process of political debate. The right course of action is always a matter of choice, never of fact. In a bureaucratic age great care must be taken that choices remain in the area of public view and participation.49 The ideals of inclusiveness, democracy and public participation remain fundamental to community-based planning, 47 Very few state planning enabling acts specifically provide for the creation of small-scale comprehensive plans. Exceptions include Montana, New Hampshire, and the District of Columbia. MONT. CODE ANN. § 76-1601(4) (2009) (requiring neighborhood plans to be consistent with the municipality’s growth policy); N.H. REV. STAT. ANN. § 674:2(III)(j) (requiring a master plan to be adopted before any neighborhood plan, and requiring that plan to be consistent with the master plan); D.C. Code § 1306.03 (2009). 48 Sheila R. Foster, The City as an Ecological Space: Social Capital and Urban Land Use, 82 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 527, 578; see also James Jennings, Race, Politics, and Community Development in U.S. Cities: Urban Planning, Community Participation, and the Roxbury Master Plan in Boston, 594 ANNALS AM. ACAD. POL. & SOC. SCI. 12, 13–14 (2004) (discussing the origins of the community-based planning movement). 49 Paul Davidoff, Advocacy and Pluralism in Planning, 34(4) J. AM. INST. PLANNERS 331 (1965), reprinted in READINGS IN PLANNING THEORY 211–12 (Scott Campbell & Susan S. Fainstein, eds., 2d ed. 2003). SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 169 and they have become core principles of the community benefits movement as well.50 Community-based planning recognizes that metropolitan plans may not be adequate to meet the needs of individual neighborhoods, as “[p]eople who are close to neighborhood issues can clearly identify community needs and advocate passionately for local concerns.”51 This type of planning is also premised on a belief that a city’s general plan will be made stronger by encompassing separately developed neighborhood plans.52 In other words, it is community-driven, rather than “top down.”53 This type of paradigm shift also requires a reappraisal of the role that professional planners play in the land use process. Gone are the “ostensibly omniscient” non-partisan 50 Gross, supra note 3, at 37–39. Department of City Planning, Community Based Planning, http://www.nyc.gov/html/dcp/html/community_planning/index.shtml (providing an overview of the city’s 197-a community planning process) (last visited Dec. 1, 2009). 52 Seattle’s neighborhood planning process has been thoroughly evaluated and it was found to be a success. The program received a 93% approval rating in a citizen survey, and the city found that it had positive impacts on the coordination of public entities, provided valuable education to citizens concerning the land use process, encouraged community-building, facilitated ongoing citizen participation, and minimized public opposition and legal challenges. The full report identified problems with the process and made suggestions for improvements. Seattle Office of City Auditor, Revisit Neighborhood Plan Implementation. http://seattle.gov/audit/docs/Published NPI.pdf (last visited Oct. 16, 2009). 53 See New York City Community-Based Planning Task Force, Planning for All New Yorkers, http://www.mas.org/planningcenter/atlas/pdf/ PlanningForAllNewYorkers_PlatformForAllNewYorkers.pdf. The Community-Based Planning Task Force, which is staffed by the Municipal Art Society, “is a coalition of grassroots organizations, citywide civic groups, community boards, elected officials, professional planners, and academics. They were motivated to act after seeing that, in some cases, plans devised by the city did not address neighborhood needs, while, at the same time, there is no effective mechanism to implement the creative, proactive plans that communities developed for their neighborhoods.” The Campaign for Community-Based Planning: Task Force, http://communitybasedplanning. wordpress.com/task-force/ (last visited Oct. 16, 2009). 51 SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 170 planners that implemented the Standard Acts; modern city planners, in addition to developing regulatory standards and synthesizing comprehensive planning goals, should act “as facilitators, community organizers, and gatherers and distributors of information . . . .”54 Because of the smaller scale of community-based plans, there are often more opportunities for citizen engagement, whether through formal public hearings, or through more informal planning workshops and charettes.55 The New York City 197-a planning process, for example, requires a number of public hearings and approval by the planning commission and city council before a community plan can be adopted.56 With the help of proactive community boards and civic organizations such as the Municipal Art Society, many plans have been shaped through community outreach efforts and collaborative planning 57 sessions. Other cities, such as Minneapolis, offer funding and 54 Alejandro Esteban Camacho, Mustering the Missing Voices: A Collaborative Model for Fostering Equality, Community Involvement and Adaptive Planning in Land Use Decisions, 24 STAN. ENVTL. L.J. 269, 292 (2005) [hereinafter Camacho II]. 55 Many cities have developed community-based planning frameworks, whether referred to as neighborhood plans, specific plans, small area plans, or community-based plans. See, e.g., San Jose Department of Planning, Building & Code Enforcement, Specific Plans, Overview, http://www.san joseca.gov/planning/spec_plan/default.asp (last visited Oct. 16, 2009); City of Columbus, Guide to Area and Neighborhood Planning, http://assets. columbus.gov/development/planning/PlanningGuide.pdf (last visited Oct. 16, 2009); Minneapolis Community Planning & Economic Development, Neighborhood Guide for Developing Planning Documents, http://www.ci. minneapolis.mn.us/cped/docs/NeighborhoodGuideforDevelopingPlanning.pdf (last visited Oct. 16, 2009); Baltimore Neighborhood Planning Program, http://www.ci.baltimore.md.us/neighborhoods/npp/index.html (last visited Oct. 16, 2009). 56 New York City Charter § 197-a (2008). 57 See, e.g., The Municipal Art Society, A Vision for Midtown’s East River Waterfront is Unveiled, Jun. 11, 2007, https://s12544.gridserver. com/viewarticle.php?id=1731&category=46 (describing the results of a charette intended to define goals for the development of the East River waterfront); GREENPOINT 197-A COMMITTEE, GREENPOINT 197-A PLAN 6 (1998), available at http://www.gwapp.org/GWAPP/01-Introduction.PDF SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 171 technical assistance for qualified community organizations that wish to build public participation and develop small area plans.58 Innovative methods to involve people from all sectors of the community are also being developed. The San Francisco Planning Department organizes walking and bus tours to encourage discussions about how residents want their neighborhoods to develop,59 and San Jose has used an online planning wiki to reach people who cannot attend (or do not want to attend) planning meetings in person.60 Community-based, small scale planning has moved a long way from the rigid and disconnected framework set up by the Standard Act, but it shares with more conventional planning models the basic idea that communities benefit from long range planning based on common goals and visions. The comprehensive plan, in the context of community-based frameworks, is a more dynamic tool, however. As law professor Alejandro Esteban Camacho explains: The collaborative model recognizes that modern land use planning and development are not static enterprises, but rather a continuing process that must be flexible in order to maximize effectiveness. Adaptable planning and permitting, which are natural extensions of a problem solving orientation, draw on a pragmatic notion of decision-making as an ongoing, iterative process of (“Through public forums, workshops, discussions, petitions, and local newspapers, collaboration between community-based groups, merchants, residents, manufacturers, new and old immigrants, and the young and the old began to revitalize the community by means of this local planning process.”). 58 See CITY OF MINNEAPOLIS, COMMUNITY PLANNING AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT DEPARTMENT, CITIZEN PARTICIPATION PROGRAM GUIDELINES (2006), available at http://www.ci.minneapolis.mn.us/cped/docs/citizen_ participation_guidelines.pdf. 59 San Francisco Planning Department, Better Neighborhoods, The Planning Process, http://www.sfgov.org/site/planning_index.asp?id=25172 (last visited Oct. 16, 2009). 60 Press Release, City of San Jose, San Jose Harnesses Web 2.0 Technology to Help Determine City’s Future and Growth (July 31, 2009), available at http://www.sanjoseca.gov/pdf/WikiplanningReleaseFINAL.pdf. SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 172 design, implementation, and evaluation. Adaptability applies not just to plans and agreements but also to the regulatory process itself; as the process matures, it is evaluated and adjusted to incorporate information such as the value of different forms of participation in facilitating informed decision-making, community cooperation, and valuable land use.61 Another significant difference between traditional and community-based comprehensive planning relates to the timing and duration of community engagement. Most state enabling statutes indicate that it is sufficient to hold one public hearing during the development of a comprehensive plan, and one hearing during the legislative process for its adoption.62 Some states, however, have specifically provided for increased public participation in the preparation and adoption of local plans.63 The American Planning Association’s Growing Smart Legislative Guidebook adopts this approach: The processes for engaging the public in planning are not made clear in many planning statutes. Requirements for public notice, public hearings, workshops, and distribution and publication of plans and development regulations are often improvised. Consequently, the public may find its role and the use of its input uncertain, and it may be suspicious of plans and decisions that emerge. Planning should be doing the opposite; it should be engaging citizens positively at all steps in the planning process, acknowledging and responding to their comments and concerns. Through collaborative 61 Camacho II, supra note 54, at 295. See, e.g., N.Y. TOWN LAW § 272-a (2009). 63 See PATRICIA E SALKIN, COLLABORATIVE PROCESSES FOR PREPARING AND ADOPTING A LOCAL COMPREHENSIVE PLAN, in MODERNIZING STATE PLANNING STATUTES: THE GROWING SMART WORKING PAPERS, vol. 2 (American Planning Association 1998) (noting a number of statutory approaches to achieving a more collaborative and inclusive planning process, including a requirement in the State of Washington for cities and counties that plan under the Growth Management Act to establish and disseminate a public participation program, see R.C.W. sec. 36.70A.140). 62 SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 173 approaches, planning should build support for outcomes that ensure that what the public wants indeed will happen.64 Community-based planning, moreover, recognizes that there is a continuing need for public participation throughout the plan’s implementation. This is especially true given the increasing popularity of development agreements, planned unit developments (PUDs), special overlay districts, and similar long-term land use controls. Unlike zoning ordinances, which are intended to be applied uniformly, the express purpose of these controls is to make the planning process more flexible and more easily tailored to specific properties. However, while “these negotiated processes provide[] the applicant-developer with substantial opportunities to participate in the decision process, public input . . . has not advanced beyond a traditional command and control model that only provides access to the process at the local agency’s final approval of the agreement.”65 To the extent that these regulatory techniques affect a community’s long-term goals, as embodied in the adaptive comprehensive plan, the community arguably should have a 66 more significant role in the decision making process. C. Environmental Justice One of the hallmarks of the environmental justice movement67 is “meaningful involvement,” which requires that: (1) people have an opportunity to participate in decisions about activities that may affect their environment and/or 64 GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at xlvii. Camacho I, supra note 1, at 17. 66 See Camacho II, supra note 54, at 297–99. 67 The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency defines environmental justice as “[t]he fair treatment and meaningful involvement of all people regardless of race, color, national origin, or income with respect to the development, implementation, and enforcement of environmental laws, regulations, and policies.” United States Environmental Protection Agency, Basic Information, http://www.epa.gov/compliance/basics/ej.html (last visited Oct. 16, 2009). 65 SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 174 health; (2) the public’s contribution can influence the regulatory agency’s decision; (3) their concerns will be considered in the decision making process; and (4) the decision makers seek out and facilitate the involvement of those potentially affected.68 While the comprehensive planning framework allows more opportunities for public participation than does an ad hoc zoning process,69 and community-based planning can encourage even more public involvement, communities are still overlooked70— especially those “discrete and insular minorities” that may be more in need of protection than other groups.71 In additional to meaningful involvement, the environmental justice movement seeks to ensure fair treatment, meaning “that no group of people should bear a disproportionate share of negative environmental consequences resulting from industrial, governmental and commercial operations or policies.”72 Fair treatment also requires an equitable distribution of environmental goods, such as parks, open spaces, and cultural and historical resources. Too often, the low income and minority communities that are excluded from the planning process are the same communities that are burdened by negative environmental impacts and provided with few environmental benefits. One model approach proposes to address this reality by 68 Id. Wideman, supra note 2, at 191–92 (“[Comprehensive] plans, especially when they result from an inclusive process, do more to foster public participation and simultaneously decrease the potential for corruption because of the diversity of opinions shaping the decisions. Some argue that ad hoc zoning, in contrast, is vulnerable to domination by factions.”). 70 See, e.g., id. at 135, 144 (“Indeed, the [New York City Planning] Commission’s processes seem designed to discourage public participation— public hearings take place at ten o’clock on Wednesday mornings, making the hearings inaccessible to those with daytime obligations such as work or family, and calendar notices and subscriptions are available at a large fee.”). 71 See United States v. Carolene Products Co., 304 U.S. 144, 153 n.4 (1938). 72 United States Environmental Protection Agency, Basic Information, http://www.epa.gov/compliance/basics/ejbackground.html (last visited Oct. 16, 2009). 69 SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 175 recommending the appointment of a public participation coordinator to work with various communities and stakeholders to invite and encourage broader participation.73 It has been noted that, “the next frontier for both the [environmental justice] movement and the focus of environmental justice scholarship . . . is land use planning.”74 California has been a pioneer in incorporating environmental justice concerns into the local land use planning process.75 Ensuring meaningful participation by all cross-sections of the community is important to give credibility and respect to the process. “Providing for active involvement by people-of-color and low-income residents in developing the goals of a locality’s comprehensive plan, at least as it relates to their own neighborhoods, will help to ensure that local zoning laws or ordinances are developed and/or amended to reflect the desires of these communities.”76 As professor Craig Anthony “Tony” Arnold argues, “land use planning and regulation foster choice, self-determination, and self-definition for local neighborhoods, not paternalism that insists that there is a single correct environmental justice goal.”77 In 1991, the First National People of Color Environmental Leadership Summit was held. The conference delegates drafted seventeen principles that better define environmental justice, and these principles have served as a pioneering document for the 73 SALKIN, supra note 63, at 151. Craig Anthony Arnold, Planning Milagros: Environmental Justice and Land Use Regulation, 76 DENV. U. L. REV. 1 (1998). 75 See Chapter 762 of the California Laws of 2001, which required the Governor’s Office of Planning and Research to publish guidelines for the incorporation of environmental justice issues in the general plans of municipalities. 76 NATIONAL ACADEMY OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION, ADDRESSING COMMUNITY CONCERNS: HOW ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE RELATES TO LAND USE PLANNING & ZONING 44 (2003), available at http://www.napawash.org/ Pubs/EJ.pdf. 77 Craig Anthony Arnold, Land Use Regulation and Environmental Justice, 30 ENVTL. L. REP. 10427 (June 2000). 74 SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 176 rapidly expanding movement.78 A number of these principles are directly applicable to community development. For example, Principle Five states: “[e]nvironmental [j]ustice affirms the fundamental right to political, economic, cultural, and environmental self-determination of all peoples.”79 This principle is related to both community planning and CBAs because both processes emphasize community-driven planning and often include the desire and promise to improve local economic and environmental situations. Principle Twelve states: “[e]nvironmental [j]ustice affirms the need for urban and rural ecological policies to clean up and rebuild our cities and rural areas in balance with nature, honoring the cultural integrity of all our communities, and provide[s] fair access for all to the full range of resources.”80 This is both an example of an aspirational goal appropriate for inclusion in local comprehensive plans, and in the CBA process, project applicants often offer environmental benefits such as park and open space and green building designs. The equitable development movement, which is closely related to the environmental justice movement, is grounded in four principles: integrating people strategies and place strategies; reducing local and regional disparities; promoting “double bottom line” investments that produce fair returns for investors as well as benefits for the community, and ensuring meaningful community participation, leadership and ownership.81 As discussed more fully below, CBAs are noted as one effective strategy to achieving equitable development.82 78 PRINCIPLES OF ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE, FIRST NATIONAL PEOPLE OF COLOR ENVIRONMENTAL LEADERSHIP SUMMIT, Apr. 6, 1996, http://www. ejnet.org/ej/principles.html. 79 Id. 80 Id. 81 Angela Glover Blackwell, Equitable Development, in BUILDING HEALTHY COMMUNITIES: A GUIDE TO COMMUNITY ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT FOR ADVOCATES, LAWYERS AND POLICYMAKERS (Roger A. Clay, Jr. & Susan R. Jones, eds., 2009). 82 Id. SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 177 III. THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS MOVEMENT The CBA movement originated in California in the late 1990s as a way to make large-scale development projects more accountable to the neighborhoods that they impact.83 The basic model is simple: community groups form a coalition and use its capacity for building public support to persuade the project developer to provide amenities and mitigations desired by local residents, business owners, and employees. After negotiations, agreements between the coalition and the developer are memorialized in a legally enforceable bilateral contract.84 In states where local governments are authorized to enter into development agreements, CBAs are often incorporated into these documents so that municipal authorities, in addition to community representatives, have the power to enforce the developer’s promises.85 A. The Overlap of CBAs and Comprehensive Plans From the outset, CBA coalitions have aspired to achieve environmental and social justice goals for the communities they represent, seeking to bind developers to commitments for living wages, local hiring policies, and increased environmental standards, among other things.86 Like community-based planning 83 Patricia Salkin & Amy Lavine, Understanding Community Benefits Agreements: Equitable Development, Social Justice and Other Considerations for Developers, Municipalities and Community Organizations, 26 UCLA J. ENVTL. L. & POL’Y 291, 301–306 (discussing the Hollywood and Highland CBA). 84 Id. at 293–94. 85 Id. at 295. Development agreements are authorized in about a dozen states. See David L. Callies & Julie A. Tappendorf, Unconstitutional Land Development Conditions and the Development Agreement Solution: Bargaining for Public Facilities After Nollan and Dolan, 51 CASE W. RES. L. REV. 663, 671 n.32 (2001). 86 See generally Julian Gross et al., Community Benefits Agreements: Making Development Projects Accountable, GOOD JOBS FIRST & THE CALIFORNIA PARTNERSHIP FOR WORKING FAMILIES (2005), available at SALKIN REVISED.DOC 178 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY programs, they have drawn attention to the fact that the planning and development review process often fails to address the needs of historically disempowered low income, minority, and nonEnglish speaking communities.87 While supporters of community-based planning have sought to change the planning and development review process to make it more inclusive and accessible, the CBA contract model allows community coalitions to bypass the traditional planning process entirely. Many of the commitments contained in CBAs relate primarily to labor standards and corporate operations (e.g., wage and hiring provisions), but other CBA promises involve the same concerns that have historically been addressed through the planning and zoning process. Provisions relating to land use, housing, transportation, environmental standards, and small business development have all become common in CBAs. In many cases, and particularly in California and other states that recognize development agreements, this has led to positive results, with community, government and private sector representatives working together in a sort of extra-publicprivate-partnership. Yet, in other cases, CBA coalitions have failed to gain the support of a broad enough cross section of community interests to be considered legitimate. This has been especially problematic in New York, where local governments are not formally authorized to engage in development negotiations.88 CBAs negotiated under such circumstances are http://www.goodjobsfirst.org/pdf/cba2005final.pdf. 87 Gross, supra note 3, at 37–38 (2008) (“Community-based organizations often assert that low-income neighborhoods, non-Englishspeaking areas, and communities of color have little voice in the development process. Laws concerning public notice and participation are sometimes poorly enforced, and official public hearings are often held during the workday.”). 88 In New York, any zoning changes offered by a city in exchange for development amenities must be undertaken according to a general incentive zoning ordinance applying to all property developments. N.Y. GEN. CITY § 81–d (2003). However, development often occurs not with the assistance of local governments, but under the aegis of either a state or local economic development authority. These quasi-public agencies have broad authority to condition various types of subsidies, including zoning overrides, on certain SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 179 often depicted as “developer-driven,” and they may interfere with the planning process rather than improving it. The following subsections describe how various CBAs have incorporated community development issues usually reserved as part of the comprehensive or neighborhood planning process. For purposes of this section, several agreements that are only arguably “CBAs” will be discussed.89 These, problematic “CBAs,” which have not encouraged inclusiveness, transparency and accountability in the development review process, are discussed in the next Part.90 1. Meaningful Public Participation and Equitable Development The community benefits movement, like community-based planning and environmental justice, has made meaningful community involvement in the development process a priority goal. The act of forming a coalition and demanding that developers be accountable to the neighborhoods that they impact is in itself a form of public participation, and the agreements obtained through CBA negotiations often include provisions to ensure that coalition groups will continue to be heard in the future. Under most CBAs, the developer must maintain continued contact with the coalition and keep it apprised of the project’s status. An advisory committee is often set up, including development conditions, and to memorialize such agreements in bilateral contracts. See N.Y. GEN. MUN. § 858 (powers of industrial development agencies); N.Y. UNCONSOL. Ch. 252 § 5 (powers of the Empire State Development Corporation). 89 CBA advocates have attempted to define the CBA concept as “a legally binding contract (or set of related contracts), setting forth a range of community benefits regarding a development project, and resulting from substantial community involvement.” Gross, supra note 3, at 37. This definition excludes all of the New York CBAs. 90 The Gateway Center at Bronx Terminal Market and Columbia University CBAs have been criticized for their lack of community involvement and it has been forcefully argued that they are not, in fact, community benefits agreements. See id. at 41–44. SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 180 developer and coalition representatives, and this committee may make recommendations on project plans or implementation measures.91 This type of framework gives community representatives a formal role in the project’s development, but a few CBAs have gone a step farther by giving coalitions a larger role in the general planning process. The coalition that negotiated the Ballpark Village CBA, for example, secured $100,000 from the developer for a professionally prepared economic impact study. The study was directed to address “the effects of new construction and rising land values in downtown San Diego on the Neighboring Communities and [to] recommend specific policy measures to encourage investment as well as protect long-term, Low-Income Local Residents from displacement.”92 In Pittsburgh, a CBA concerning the new Penguins Arena included funding for the creation of a neighborhood master plan, which will cover issues relating to land use, community services, parks and open space, housing, social and environmental impacts, urban design, education, 91 The Staples Center CBA, for example, established an Advisory Committee to provide input to the developer about the construction management plan, the traffic management plan, the waste management plan, the neighborhood traffic protection plan, and other environmental concerns (e.g. pedestrian safety, air quality, green building). Staples Center, COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT, at sec. XI, A-13 (2001), available at http://www.communitybenefits.org/downloads/Los%20Angeles%20Sports%2 0and%20Entertainment%20District%20Project.pdf [hereinafter Staples CBA]; see also Dearborn Street Implementation Committee, EXECUTED SETTLEMENT AGREEMENT, at art. 5, http://www.communitybenefits.org/article.php?id= 1464 [hereinafter Dearborn Street CBA]; Hunters Point Implementation Committee, COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT, at 14 (2008), http://www. communitybenefits.org/downloads/Bayview%20Hunters%20Point%20CBA.pd f [hereinafter Hunters Point CBA]; Pacoima Community Oversight Committee, PLAZA PACOIMA PROJECT COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT, at sec. X [hereinafter Pacoima Plaza CBA]; Park East Community Advisory Committee, PARK EAST REDEVELOPMENT COMPACT, http://www.community benefits.org/downloads/PERC.pdf [hereinafter Park East Redevelopment Compact]. 92 Ballpark Village Project, COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT, at 12 (2005), available at http://www.communitybenefits.org/downloads/Ballpark% 20Village%20CBA.pdf [hereinafter Ballpark Village CBA]. SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 181 economic development, traffic, arts and culture, historic preservation and uses for vacant property. The Penguins, moreover, agreed to postpone the submission of further development proposals until after the plan’s completion.93 The site-specific nature of CBAs also offers an effective way to impose mitigation requirements on developers in order to ensure a more equitable distribution of negative environmental impacts.94 Many CBAs, for example, include provisions to limit construction impacts such as diesel exhaust, particulate emissions and dust.95 The CBA covering the LAX airport 93 One Hill Neighborhood Coalition & Sports and Exhibition Authority of Pittsburg, HILL DISTRICT COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT, at 5–6 (2008), http://www.communitybenefits.org/article.php?id=1463 [hereinafter Penguins CBA]. To be specific, the Penguins only agreed to postpone further development proposals until February 2010. 94 See Larissa Larsen, The Pursuit of Responsible Development: Addressing Anticipated Benefits and Unwanted Burdens through Community Benefits Agreements 6 (Ctr. For Local State, and Urban Policy Working Paper Series, No. 9, 2009) (stating that “spatial inequity is central to the environmental justice movement” and “relevant to the site-specific nature of CBAs”) (citing DAVID HARVEY, JUSTICE, NATURE AND THE GEOGRAPHY OF DIFFERENCE (Blackwell Publishing 1996)). 95 See, e.g., Atlantic Yards, COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT, at 35, http://www.buildbrooklyn.org/pr/cba.pdf [hereinafter Atlantic Yards CBA] (requiring a plan for minimizing truck idling); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 6, 17, 22, 24–25, 28, 30 (requiring contaminated soils will not be shipped to treatment facilities in urban neighborhoods or that have adverse compliance histories, restrictions in pesticide use in landscaping, prohibition on onsite incineration, minimized idling, and designated construction routes); Pacoima Plaza CBA, supra note 91 (requiring trucks to minimize idling, and requiring the developer to give preference to contractors that use low emission equipment); LAX Master Plan Program, COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT, at 17, 20, 22, 28, 29, available at http://www.laxmasterplan. org/commBenefits/pdf/LAX_CBA_Final.pdf [hereinafter LAX CBA] (requiring electrified cargo gates to reduce emissions, $500,000 to replace high emission equipment, requirement to phasing out airport vehicles and replacing them with low emission or alternative vehicles, no idling, that for diesel equipment best available emissions control devices be used for diesel equipment as well as ultra low sulfur fuel, that rock crushing will be located away from the communities neighboring LAX in order to reduce dust, designated construction routes); Columbia University, COMMUNITY BENEFITS SALKIN REVISED.DOC 182 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY expansion also included special protections for communities located next to the airport, which had long suffered from the airport’s noise and pollution. The airport authority agreed to fund an air quality study and a health impact study, the latter focusing on upper respiratory diseases and hearing loss. Nighttime departures were also restricted to limit noise, and more than $4 million was allotted for soundproofing nearby homes and schools.96 Since the LAX CBA was completed in 2004, air quality monitoring requirements have been included in several other agreements.97 For industrial projects that create extensive negative environmental impacts, Good Neighbor Agreements (“GNAs”) can also be used to mandate protections for nearby communities.98 GNAs use the same community-corporation contract framework as CBAs, but they typically focus on the complex technical mitigation solutions required by heavy industrial facilities such as oil refineries, mines, chemical plants, foundries, and large-scale agricultural operations. Most GNAs require information about plant operations to be made available AGREEMENT 34, http://www.columbia.edu/cu/gca/pdf-files/CBAAgreement .pdf [hereinafter Columbia CBA] (ultra low sulfur fuels); Purina Site Development, Community Benefits Agreement, http://amy.m.lavine. googlepages.com/FINALPDFLongfellowCBA-Feb.242008.pdf [hereinafter Longfellow CBA]; COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT: CONCERNING THE CHRISTINA AVENUE COMPOSTING FACILITY BY AND BETWEEN PENINSULA COMPOST CO., LLC AND THE S. WILMINGTON COALITION 9–10 (2007) [hereinafter Peninsula Compost CBA] (prohibiting truck traffic in adjacent residential communities and requiring that trucks must be covered). 96 LAX CBA, supra note 95, at 6. 97 In the Gateway Center CBA, for instance, the developer agreed to work with the New York City Department of Environmental Protection to test for particulate emissions. Gateway Center at Bronx Terminal Market, COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT 33 [hereinafter Gateway Center CBA], available at http://www.bronxgateway.com/documents/copy_of_community_ benefits_agreement/Signed_CBA_2_1_06.pdf; see also Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92. 98 See generally CPN, Good Neighbor Agreements: A Tool For Environmental and Social Justice, http://www.cpn.org/topics/environment/ goodneighbor.html (last visited Oct. 16, 2009) (explaining the purpose, benefits, and general scope of good neighbor agreements). SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 183 to the public, and they often require facilities to be open to inspection by designated community members or third parties. Other provisions directly restrict corporate signatories. They may be required to formulate accident prevention and preparedness plans, covering such contingencies as chemical spills and fires, and they may have to implement various pollution prevention strategies. Although some GNAs have included provisions relating to local hiring, union neutrality, and funding for health centers and parks,99 they do not usually address the variety of issues covered by most CBAs.100 Another difference is that some GNAs are voluntary agreements that seek primarily to build relationships and create dialogues about pollution reduction and community health,101 whereas the CBA movement makes enforceability a paramount concern.102 The close connection between CBAs, GNAs, and environmental justice is evident in Connecticut’s 2008 law regarding environmental justice communities103—the only general 99 The Unocal GNA included funding for health studies and for a clinic, a commitment to improve the site’s landscaping and construct a bike path, funding for vocational training at the local high school, a hiring preference for local employees, $4.5 million for transportation infrastructure improvements, and $300,000 annually for 15 years to go into a community fund. Good Neighbor Agreement: Unocal (on file with author). A promise to donate certain conservation easements was included in the Stillwater Mine GNA, as well as a promise that any land acquired by the company after the GNA was signed would be encumbered with a conservation easement restricting residential subdivisions. The GNA also limited permissible locations for mine-sponsored housing. Good Neighbor Agreement: Stillwater Mining Company, http://www.northernplains.org/files/2005amendedgna (last visited Dec. 1, 2009). 100 See Gross, supra note 3, at 40, n.22. 101 See, e.g., The Southeast Como Improvement Association: Ritrama Agreement, http://secomo.org/drupal/index.php?q=ritrama-agreement (last visited Dec. 1, 2009); The Southeast Como Improvement Association: Rock Tenn. Agreement, http://secomo.org/drupal/index.php?q=rock-tennagreement (last visited Dec. 1, 2009). 102 Gross, supra note 3, at 39 (2007–2008) (“[L]egal enforceability should be a prerequisite for something to be termed a CBA.”). 103 Conn. P.A. 08-94, S. 1, (codified as CONN. GEN. STAT. § 22a–20a (2008)). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 184 state or local law yet to be enacted that attempts to regulate CBA-like agreements.104 The statute defines a “community environmental benefit agreement” (“CEBA”) as: [A] written agreement entered into by a municipality and an owner or developer of real property whereby the owner or developer agrees to develop real property that is to be used for any new or expanded affecting facility and to provide financial resources for the purpose of the mitigation, in whole or in part, of impacts reasonably related to the facility, including, but not limited to, impacts on the environment, traffic, parking and noise.105 Unlike CBAs, these CEBAs are only implicated in the construction of “affecting facilities,” which are defined as heavy 106 industrial facilities that are major pollution generators. While a local government can enter into a CEBA regarding any affecting facility, the law’s requirements apply only when an affecting facility is being located in an “environmental justice community,”107 defined as a census tract designated as distressed under state law or with at least 30% of residents at or below 200% of the poverty line.108 When the law does apply, the developer must consult with the local government regarding the need for a CEBA,109 which may include provisions for on and off site mitigations and “[f]unding for activities such as environmental education, diesel pollution reduction, construction 104 In Milwaukee and Atlanta, local laws have been passed requiring community benefits to be included in certain developments. While the Connecticut legislation is a general law, applying throughout the state, both the Milwaukee and Atlanta CBA are limited to specific sites within their jurisdictions. See Salkin & Lavine, supra note 83, at 319; Amy Lavine, Atlanta Beltline Community Benefits, COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS BLOG, May 19, 2008 (updated Aug. 16, 2009), http://communitybenefits. blogspot.com/2008/05/atlanta-beltline-community-benefits.html. 105 CONN. GEN. STAT. § 22a–20a(a)(4) (2008). 106 CONN. GEN. STAT. § 22a–20a(a)(2) (2008) (defining “affecting facility”). 107 CONN. GEN. STAT. § 22a–20a(b)(1) (2008). 108 CONN. GEN. STAT. § 22a–20a(a)(1). 109 CONN. GEN. STAT. § 22a–20a(b)(1). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 185 of biking and walking trails, staffing for parks, urban forestry, support for community gardens or any other negotiated benefit to the environment in the environmental justice community.”110 The developer is also required to file a “meaningful public participation plan,”111 which should cover issues relating to “appropriate opportunities” for public participation, methods for seeking out and facilitating public input, and assurances that public comments will be considered as part of the agency’s decision.112 2. Sustainable Development and Pedestrian/Transit Oriented Design As the public’s awareness of sustainability issues has grown in recent years, planners have increasingly begun to incorporate into community plans provisions encouraging green building, energy and water efficiency, alternative transportation and alternative energy.113 CBAs, too, have attempted to address many of these issues. The most common sustainability features found in CBAs relate to green building standards. Typically, they require the developer to meet the eligibility requirements for LEED certification.114 Some require actual certification, usually at the Silver level or lower, while others require only that the project be eligible for LEED certification.115 Specific green building 110 CONN. GEN. STAT. § 22a–20a(c). CONN. GEN. STAT. § 22a–20a(b)(1) (2008). 112 CONN. GEN. STAT. § 22a-20a(a)(3) (2008) (defining “meaningful public participation”). 113 Salkin, supra note 46. 114 U.S. Green Building Council, LEED, http://www.usgbc.org/Display Page.aspx?CategoryID=19 (last visited Oct. 16, 2009). 115 See, e.g., Pacoima Plaza CBA, supra note 91 (requiring LEED silver); Penguins CBA, supra note 93, at 17 (requiring LEED certification); LAX CBA, supra note 95, at 29 (requiring LEED to the extent practicable); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 8 (requiring LEED or Minnesota standards); Gateway CBA, supra note 97, at 31 (requiring LEED Silver goal); Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 32 (requiring minimum LEED 111 SALKIN REVISED.DOC 186 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY features may also be set forth in the CBA, whether part of the LEED system or not. The Ballpark Village CBA, for example, requires that windows must use bird-reflective glass,116 and the Columbia University CBA specifies that the university will “evaluate the use of green roof technology and managed vegetated areas” as a way to control storm water runoff.117 The Minneapolis Longfellow Station CBA stands out as an example of sustainability planning in CBAs because of its emphasis on transit oriented design (TOD) and amenities for pedestrians and bicyclists. Similar to the broad goals and principles that are typically included in comprehensive plans, the CBA recites a list of guiding TOD principles,118 as well as more specific project requirements. In order to promote alternative transportation and advance the project’s TOD goals, the developer agreed in the CBA to provide free one-month transit passes to residential tenants and to ensure that transit fare can be purchased onsite.119 The development must also include bicycle storage and parking facilities, and dedicated parking spaces for Zipcars.120 To discourage automobile use, the CBA limits parking to a maximum of one space per residential unit and 4.5 spaces for every 1,000 square feet of commercial space, and it requires parking spaces to be leased separately from residential units.121 Walkability and “placemaking” principles are also included in the Longfellow Station CBA to promote human scale silver); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 5 (requiring LEED certified minimum, developer must try for better); Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 35 (requiring “prudent environmentally sound building practices”). 116 Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 7. It also requires pest management, including using naturally pest-repellent vegetation and less toxic pesticides. Id. at 31. 117 Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 34. 118 Longfelllow CBA, supra note 95, at 5–6. The guiding principles include: urban intensity; height, density, and public/green space; economic vitality; urban form; urban uses; retail location; reverse the normal parking rules; walkability; transit connectivity; and neighborhood connectivity. 119 Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 14. 120 Id. at 14–15 121 Id. at 14–15 SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 187 design.122 Pedestrians are favored by requirements for paths,123 wayfinding signs,124 landscaped public gathering spaces,125 and safety measures such as traffic calming infrastructure.126 Sustainability principles also play a significant role in the Columbia University CBA, which states that: In decisions regarding the Project Area, [the university] shall be guided by the following goals: protecting the biosphere; the sustainable use of renewable natural resources; the reduction of waste and the safe disposal of waste; energy conservation; greenhouse gas emission reduction; environmental risk reduction to [Columbia] staff, students and the surrounding community; and correcting damage, if any; reducing the use of products that cause environmental damage; and reducing impacts to air quality in the surrounding area, with a particular sensitivity to the impacts to people suffering from asthma.127 Among other things, the CBA includes promises to use energy efficient appliances, mitigate the heat island effect, reduce storm water runoff, and plant street trees.128 122 Id. at 18–19. Pedestrian-scale design requirements are also included in the Gateway Center at Terminal Market CBA. Gateway Center CBA, supra note 97, at 32–33, 35 (providing specifically for street trees, lighting, wide sidewalks). 123 Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 15. 124 Id. at 16; see also Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 7 (providing for way-finding signs). 125 Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 16–17. 126 Id. at 14–15. 127 Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 32. 128 Id. at 32–33; see also Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 7 (providing for “commercially feasible” development of passive infiltration for storm water); SunQuest, COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT, at 3, http://www.communitybenefits.org/article.php?id=1474 [hereinafter SunQuest CBA] (requiring roofs and pavement must be light in color to avoid the heat island effect); Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 10–11 (ensuring construction of permeable sidewalks). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 188 3. Community Facilities and Neighborhood Improvements Comprehensive plans often contain a community facilities element that discusses public buildings, infrastructure, and “those facilities that contribute to the cultural life or physical and mental health and personal growth of a local government’s residents (e.g., hospitals, clinics, libraries, and arts centers).”129 Most CBAs include some type of community amenity that would fall within this planning area, such as dedicated space and funding for community centers,130 neighborhood improvements,131 open/public spaces,132 child care facilities133 and medical 129 GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at 7-111. See, e.g., Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 6, 9–10 (5,000 square feet for community nonprofits and community events; $200,000 for a community center and Vietnamese cultural center); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 17 (space for public information display, a community room for meeting, and 500 square feet for nonprofits at reduced rent); Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 38–39 (space for Community Board 9); MARLTON SQUARE REDEVELOPMENT PROJECT DEVELOPER COMMUNITY BENEFITS PROGRAM 3, available at http://www.communitybenefits.org/downloads/cba_marlton square.pdf (space for community meetings and other community activities); Penguins CBA, supra note 93, at 11 (commitment to assist YMCA to develop and sustain a multi-purpose center for youth, family and seniors in the community); Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 28 (developer will provide child care, youth and senior centers). 131 Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 9 ($50,000 for right of way improvements); SunQuest CBA, supra note 128, at 4–5 ($150,000 for a neighborhood improvement fund; youth center). 132 Staples CBA, supra note 91, at A-2–3 (needs assessment and $1 million for parks; street level public plaza); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 16–17 (landscaped public gathering places); Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 30 (6 acres of open space). 133 Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 38 (5,000 square feet for a nonprofit day care center for income eligible families); North Hollywood Mixed-Use Redevelopment Project, COMMUNITY BENEFITS PROGRAM 2 (Nov. 2001), available at http://amy.m.lavine.googlepages.com/NoHo20CBA.pdf (developer will build onsite childcare center, find a tenant, and require the tenant to provide care for at least 50 low-moderate income families). 130 SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 189 centers.134 Several CBAs also require the developer to either market project space to businesses needed by the community, such as grocery stores and banks,135 or to restrict the availability of project space to businesses like pawnshops that have been deemed detrimental to the community.136 4. Housing Housing is an important component in both comprehensive plans137 and CBAs. When CBAs cover projects involving substantial housing components, they typically require the developer to build more affordable units than would otherwise be required.138 As an alternative to including affordable housing 134 See, e.g., Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 39 (funding to expand existing medical facilities); Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 26 (developing a health care center providing comprehensive quality primary care). 135 Pacoima Plaza CBA, supra note 91, at 9 (developer will market space to traditional banks); Penguins CBA, supra note 93, at 8 ($2 million for a grocery store that must include a pharmacy and a selection of healthy foods); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 12 (developer will use good faith efforts to rent to a grocery store). 136 See Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 7 (no payday lenders or pawnshops); Pacoima CBA, supra note 95 (no payday lenders); Gateway Center CBA, supra note 97, at 34 (no Wal-Mart); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 18 (no hotel); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 12–13 (no big boxes or stores that do not accept food stamps); Front Range Economic Strategy Center, GATES-CHEROKEE REDEVELOPMENT COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENT (2008), http://communitybenefits.blogspot.com/2008/ 01/gates-cherokee-redevelopment-cba.html [hereinafter Gates Cherokee CBA] (no big boxes). 137 See GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE HANDBOOK, supra note 1, at ch. 4 (housing element). 138 See Steve Brandt, Minneapolis Neighborhood Makes a Deal and History, STARTRIBUNE.COM, Mar. 4, 2008, http://www.startribune.com/ local/16240642.html (noting that the Longfellow Station CBA requires more affordable housing than the Minneapolis inclusionary zoning ordinance). If a project is not subject to inclusionary housing minimums, CBAs generally call for the developer to maximize the amount of affordable housing included in the project. See, e.g., Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 8 (200 of 400 SALKIN REVISED.DOC 190 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY within the project, some developers have committed to building offsite affordable housing in order to mitigate the displacement and/or gentrification caused by the project.139 Most CBA housing provisions specify levels of housing affordability and the length of time for which units must remain affordable.140 Some provide requirements for the types of units must be affordable); Staples CBA, supra note 91, at A-9 (20% affordable); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 7 (30% affordable housing); Gates Cherokee CBA, supra note 136 (10% of for sale units and 20% of rental units); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 10 (developer will maximize affordable housing). 139 See, e.g., Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 10 ($20 million for affordable housing to address the impact of the project); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 11 ($1.5 million for affordable housing in neighboring communities); Hunters Point CBA, supra note 91, at 8 ($27.3 million for a “Community First Housing Fund” to buy market rate properties inside and outside the project for income eligible residents); Grand Avenue Committee, GRAND AVENUE COMMUNITY BENEFITS PROJECT (2008), http://www. grandavenuecommittee.org/community.html [hereinafter Grand Avenue] (revolving loan fund of at least $750,000 for affordable housing development); Staples CBA, supra note 91, at A-11 ($650,000 revolving loan fund for affordable housing development). 140 Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 9 (120 of the 200 units must be affordable at AMI 50% and the other 80 must be affordable at AMI 80%; 50 years affordability); Hunters Point CBA, supra note 91, at 7 (providing a schedule of housing affordability requirements); Grand Avenue, supra note 139 (half of the affordable units will be priced at not more than 80% AMI, and the other half at 50%; affordability is required for 55 years for rental units and 45 years for for sale units); Staples CBA, supra note 91, at A-10 (30% of affordable units will be for 50% AMI, 35% will be for 51–60% AMI, and 35% will be for 61–80% AMI; minimum 30 years affordability); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 7 (20% of all units to be affordable at 50% AMI and 10% to be affordable at 40–60% AMI; affordability required for 30 years); Gates Cherokee CBA, supra note 136 (units must remain affordable for at least 40 years); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 10 (average AMI of affordable units can be no more than 47%); Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 24 (units are to be affordable for 30 years); Oak to Ninth Community Benefits Coalition and the Redevelopment Agency, OAK TO NINTH COOPERATION AGREEMENT, at 3 (2006) http://www.urbanstrategies. org/programs/econopp/documents/FinalOaktoNinthCooperationAgreeementwit hCoalitionfinalexecution.pdf [hereinafter Oak to Ninth CBA] (“[A]ll Project SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 191 affordable units to be included in the development (e.g., different unit sizes, rental versus for sale units, senior restricted housing, etc.)141 and the location of affordable units, both in relation to the project and in relation to other affordable housing units.142 Other CBAs give preferences for affordable units to people displaced by the project, low-income residents or local residents.143 CBAs may also seek to expedite the construction of Units shall be provided at no greater than an Affordable Rent to households earning from 25 percent to 60 percent of Area Median Income for at least 55 years.”). 141 See, e.g., Oak to Ninth CBA, supra note 140, at 3 (no more than 25% of affordable units can be senior restricted, at least 30% must be threebedroom units, and at least 20% must be two-bedroom units); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 7 (requiring a mix of studios, and one, two and three bedroom units); Gates Cherokee CBA, supra note 136 (requiring 10% of for sale units and 20% of rentals to be affordable); Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91 (requiring 50 units of affordable “family housing”); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 10–11 (some units in the offsite affordable housing project must be reserved for seniors); Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 25 (10% of affordable units reserved for seniors); Hunters Point CBA, supra note 91, at 9–10 (average affordable unit size of 2.5 bedrooms and requiring some units to be for seniors or disabled residents). 142 See, e.g., Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 7 (prohibiting any one building from containing more than 65% affordable housing so as “to prevent a concentration of affordable housing in any particular building in the development”); Gates Cherokee CBA, supra note 136 (buildings are to be inclusionary); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 10 (75% of the affordable units at one building will be 2 or 3 bedroom units, other building will be devoted to single rooms and transitional housing); Staples CBA, supra note 91, at A-10 (affordable units will be either on or offsite, but offsite units will be within a 3 mile radius); Oak to Ninth CBA, supra note 140, at 5 (permitting the redevelopment agency to construct a maximum of 77 offsite affordable units and limiting them to the immediate area). 143 See, e.g., Staples CBA, supra note 91, at A-16 (giving priority given to displaced residents); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 11 (requiring that 10% of the restricted units will be targeted to households with at least one person who has worked in downtown San Diego for one year, 60% shall be targeted to people from neighboring communities, 30% may be targeted to anybody); Hunters Point CBA, supra note 91, at 9–10 (requiring priority marketing for the affordable units for existing local residents, displaced residents, etc.); Grand Avenue, supra note 139 (giving priority for rentals for displaced residents). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 192 affordable units by requiring them to be finished before work is started on other parts of the project.144 5. Aesthetics and Building Design Community character is often shaped by a neighborhood’s “look,” and for this reason, aesthetics and architecture often play a role in community planning.145 While most CBAs do not contain detailed aesthetic or design regulations, a number of CBAs do address specific aesthetic issues. Several include limitations on signs and blank facades, both of which can give a community a dull or garish appearance.146 For similar reasons, 147 the the Pacoima Plaza CBA prohibits barred windows, Peninsula Compost CBA requires project facilities to be screened from view,148 and the Longfellow Station agreement 149 prohibits vinyl siding and drive through windows. In contrast to these preemptive measures, other CBAs include provisions intended to affirmatively foster community character, such as space and funding requirements for public 144 See, e.g., Oak to Ninth CBA, supra note 140, at 5 (requiring construction of any offsite units to be commenced prior to commercial parts of the project); Hunters Point CBA, supra note 91, at 7; Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 8 (stating the city will not be obligated to grant a certificate of occupancy for the retail space until the developers can show that construction has commenced on at least 200 housing units, including at least 80 affordable units; developer agrees that within 4 years of the issuance of the certificate of occupancy, construction must be commenced on the other 200 units). 145 See GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE HANDBOOK, supra note 1, at 7168 to 7-172 (community design element). 146 Gateway Center CBA, supra note 97, at 32 (requiring that there not be any blank walls); Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 6 (requiring facades of stores are unique and distinct and specific sign restrictions); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 6. 147 Pacoima Plaza CBA, supra note 91, at 7. 148 See also Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 19 (requiring screening of machinery, loading docks, and trash areas). 149 Id. SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 193 art.150 Recognizing the unique character of Seattle’s Little Saigon neighborhood, the Dearborn CBA (although the project was later cancelled151) included $200,000 for the construction of a Vietnamese cultural center, and provisions intended to help existing small businesses run by Vietnamese merchants.152 Similarly, Columbia agreed to preserve several of the neighborhood’s historic buildings and to help create a multidisciplinary historic preservation and development strategy.153 “Placemaking” is an important part of the Longfellow Station CBA. While the design guides are in part intended to promote walking and transit use, as noted above, they are also intended to “encourage interaction and connection at a human scale . . . through creation of a welcoming, safe, and accessible environment.”154 The project is to “be urban, not suburban, in feel and function” and buildings must be “designed to have a pedestrian feel at street level. Scale, massing and relationships of buildings shall be designed to relate to the users (not overwhelm the users).”155 Additionally, the project is to be designed so as to facilitate outdoor dining and shopping, and high quality exterior building materials are required in order to 150 See, e.g., Pacoima Plaza CBA, supra note 91 (developer will comply with CRA’s public art policy); Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 36 (5,000 square feet of space for use by local artists); Ballpark Village CBA, supra note 92, at 12 (requires a good faith effort to use local artists); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 17 (space for public art). 151 Emily Heffter, $300M Project at Seattle Goodwill Site Canceled, SEATTLE TIMES, Apr. 24, 2009, http://seattletimes.nwsource.com/html/ localnews/2009116421_webgoodwill24.html. 152 Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 6, 9–10 (70,000 square feet set aside for small retail stores that each occupy less than 5,000 square feet and at least 5,000 square feet to one or more non-profit organizations who primarily provide services to the Vietnamese Community); see also Stuart Eskenazi, Coalition Talks Reach Deal on Goodwill Site, SEATTLE TIMES, http://seattletimes.nwsource.com/html/localnews/2008152450_dearborn02m.ht ml. 153 Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 39–40. 154 Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 18. 155 Id. at 19. SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 194 establish “a sense of permanency.”156 6. Parking & Traffic CBAs do not generally include detailed transportation plans, but some agreements have included provisions relating to parking, traffic and transit facilities. (Unlike the TOD provisions described above, which are intended to promote transit and discourage driving, these transportation requirements are aimed at mitigating congestion and improving infrastructure.) Examples of transportation-related community benefits include the establishment of a residential parking permit program,157 the 158 construction of additional parking facilities, and subway, bus stop and other infrastructure improvements.159 The Columbia CBA also authorizes funding for a transportation needs assessment study, which may cover such issues as public transportation, parking needs, traffic calming devices, and air quality.160 7. Small Business Development Comprehensive plans frequently address economic development,161 and “[a] growing number of communities are including in their comprehensive plans an intention to preserve and strengthen locally owned businesses, limit commercial development to the downtown or other existing retail districts, 156 Id. See, e.g., Staples CBA, supra note 91, at A-3. 158 See, e.g., Peninsula Compost CBA, supra note 95, at 4 (neighborhood parking lot); Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 36 (adding 72 public parking spaces). 159 See, e.g., Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 9 ($150,000 for traffic mitigation); Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 35–36 (subway and bus stop improvements). 160 Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 35. 161 See, e.g., GROWING SMART LEGISLATIVE GUIDEBOOK, supra note 1, at 7-127 to 7-135. 157 SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 195 and restrict the proliferation of corporate chains.”162 With or without the guidance of such policies, community coalitions have often sought CBA benefits to encourage the growth of small and local businesses. Many CBAs set goals for awarding contracts to local businesses, and these provisions usually include a preference for minority and women owned businesses—frequently referred to as minority-owned business enterprises (“MBEs”), womenowned business enterprises (“WBEs”) or minority-womenowned business enterprises (“MWBEs”).163 CBAs relating to projects with retail or commercial components have included space set-asides for small and local businesses164 and in a few CBAs, big boxes and large chain stores have been effectively prohibited by retail size caps.165 162 See New Rules, Comprehensive Plans, http://www.newrules.org/ retail/rules/comprehensive-plans (last visited Dec. 1, 2009). 163 See, e.g., Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 17–18 (goals to award at least 5% of preconstruction contracts (e.g., architectural, engineering, legal) to MBEs and 3% to WBEs (by total value of contracts), goals to award at least 20% of construction contracts to MBEs and 10% to WBEs (by total value of contracts), with a preference for community based businesses, goals to award at least 20% of post construction purchasing and service contracts to MWBEs). 164 See, e.g., Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 19 (15% set aside for small businesses, with below market rents); Dearborn Street CBA, supra note 91, at 6 (70,000 square feet set aside for small retail stores greater than 5,000 square feet and at least two non-formula businesses); Gateway Center CBA, supra note 97, at 29 (18,000 square feet for small businesses); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 12–13 (national chains can occupy no more than 70% of the project and 10% must be reserved for “community based small businesses”); San Jose CIM Project Community Benefits Agreement 121–22 (Dec. 12, 2002), http://www.communitybenefits.org/ article.php?id=1476 (goals of 30% San Jose retailers and 30% regional retailers, with a set aside of 10% of the available retail space for existing small business in the downtown); Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 22 (18,000 square foot set aside for small businesses). 165 See, e.g., Gates Cherokee CBA, supra note 136, at 2 (size cap at 75,000 square feet); Gateway Center CBA, supra note 97 (manuscript at 34) (no Wal-Mart); Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 19 (large retail cap at 30,000 square feet); Columbia CBA, supra note 95, at 22 (retail rental size SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 196 Other benefits to small and local businesses include low interest loan programs,166 provisions requiring contracts to be unbundled (to level the playing field for smaller businesses),167 and programs to better inform local businesses about the project’s business opportunities.168 The Penguins Arena CBA, for example, will seek to increase community business involvement in the project by requiring the developer to notify the coalition of pre-bid activities and meetings with contractors. Local business owners will also be invited to business opportunity workshops provided by the Penguins, which will help them to take advantage of opportunities for concessions, retail space, suppliers, vendors and subcontractors.169 IV. DO PRIVATE CBAS USURP THE PUBLIC PLANNING PROCESS? The inclusion in CBAs of community amenities that resemble items normally found in comprehensive plans and/or implementing regulations raises a number of critical community planning issues that have not yet been addressed. A. Are CBAs Another Type of Community-Based Plan? When considered as a whole, CBAs are not synonymous with comprehensive land use plans or smaller scale communitybased plans. CBAs involve issues not contemplated by planning documents, such as increased wage requirements, union neutrality, local hiring goals, and job training programs. These provisions, moreover, are core issues of the community benefits 170 CBA coalitions also have the potential to movement. cap at 2,500 square feet). 166 See, e.g., Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 20; LAX CBA, supra note 95, at 31 (revolving loan fund for small businesses). 167 See, e.g., Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 20. 168 See, e.g., Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 20–21 (targeted outreach to local small businesses and “Meet the General Contractor” meetings, a series of technical assistance workshops for local MWBEs). 169 See Penguins CBA, supra note 93, at 12–13. 170 See, e.g., CommunityBenefits.org, A New Urban Agenda for SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 197 encourage more public participation than traditional planning processes by building a sense of community empowerment. Rather than the development of the community vision being facilitated by a government employed planning staff, CBAs are usually developed and facilitated by members of the impacted community.171 Community-based planning and coalition organizing have much in common, however, as both seek out diverse stakeholders using non-conventional outreach techniques. As project-specific documents, the impact of CBAs is also spatially limited,172 unlike comprehensive plans, which apply to America: Rebuild the Middle Class, http://communitybenefits.org/downloads/ A%20New%20Urban%20Agenda%20for%20America.pdf (last visited Oct. 15, 2009) (“The standard menu of progressive urban policy initiatives focuses on addressing identified needs of poor families by reestablishing the social safety net and improving job training and education programs. The new urban agenda adds an important and often missing component by addressing one of the main causes of urban poverty: the prevalence of low-paying, lowquality employment and the dearth of middle-class job opportunities.”). 171 However, in states where the government is more directly involved with CBAs, such as in California, the planning staff may be more intimately involved in the process. For example, staff at the Los Angeles Community Redevelopment Agency are routinely involved in the development of CBAs. 172 The requirement that CBAs be limited to one development is intended to distinguish the tool from: redevelopment plans, general plans, specific plans, zoning laws, and other land use documents that might encourage or require specified community benefits for particular geographic areas. This requirement also excludes from the definition of CBA single-issue policies that cover a range of projects, such as typical inclusionary housing policies or local hiring policies. Gross, supra note 3, at 39. However, legislative CBA provisions may require multiple developers to provide specific community benefits lobbied for by the community, as in the Milwaukee Park East Redevelopment Compact. This document requires the developers of county-owned land to provide living wages and job training programs, and to use green building techniques. Park East Redevelopment Compact, supra note 91. See also Amy Lavine, Milwaukee Park East Redevelopment CBA, COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS BLOG, http://communitybenefits.blogspot.com/2008/01/ milwaukee-park-east-redevelopment-cba.html (Jan. 3, 2008). Alternatively, a legislative CBA provision may require multiple developers to negotiate CBAs in the future. This approach was taken in relation to Atlanta’s Beltline SALKIN REVISED.DOC 198 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY all of the residents and businesses in a given city or metropolitan area. CBAs that involve commitments of planning-related amenities and accommodations may be placed on the spectrum close to small-scale comprehensive plans, especially when they include the types of broad policy statements that are commonly used to guide community-based plans. Despite the similarities between CBAs and small-scale community-based plans, the unregulated CBA negotiation process should not be permitted to displace thorough and accountable government planning. In this regard, the CBA for Atlantic Yards, a proposed arena project and mega-development located in Brooklyn, has been particularly maligned. The CBA has demonstrated that specious appearances of community involvement can legitimate departures from the normal planning process when, in fact, the CBA’s effect may be to make development projects less accountable, less transparent, and more exclusionary than they otherwise would be. In the case of Atlantic Yards, the project’s government partner, a state economic development authority, overrode all of the local zoning and planning laws in order to expedite the development.173 As a result, the project’s approval was left 174 primarily to the state authority’s unelected board, with no city project, requiring developers that accept financial incentives to “reflect, through the development agreements or funding agreements that accompany such projects, certain community benefit principles[.]” ATLANTA, GA., ORDINANCE 05-O-1733 § 19 (2005). 173 Lance Freeman, Atlantic Yards and the Perils of Community Benefits Agreements, PLANETIZEN, May 5, 2007, http://www.planetizen.com/node/ 24335. Authority for the override of local zoning and planning laws is found in the New York State Urban Development Corporation Act, N.Y. UNCONSOL. LAW § 6255 (2006). 174 The project also required a land deal with the Metropolitan Transportation Authority, another unelected authority, as well as approvals from the Public Authorities Control Board (“PACB”), which does include several representatives from the state legislature. See N.Y. State Gov’t website, About the Public Authorities Control Board, http://www.budget. state.ny.us/agencyGuide/pacb/aboutPACB.html. The PACB’s role is limited, however, to approving project financing; it is not authorized to make planning and development decisions. SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 199 officials ever having had a chance to review the project and condition or reject it.175 The CBA, moreover, was finalized before an environmental impact statement had been prepared for the project, meaning that the CBA signatories may have been unaware of the extent of the project’s impacts.176 The Atlantic Yards CBA does include promises of significant community amenities, such as hundreds of affordable housing units, open space, job training, and a health center, but it has been widely criticized as being unrepresentative of the community.177 Negotiations were conducted secretly, with many 175 Normally, the city’s uniform land use review process would give local community boards, the borough president, the planning commission, and the city council a chance to review the development application. New York City Dept. of City Planning, The Uniform Land Use Review Procedure (ULURP), http://www.nyc.gov/html/dcp/html/luproc/ulpro.shtml (last visited Dec. 1, 2009). 176 The Atlantic Yards CBA was signed in 2005. Atlantic Yards CBA, supra note 95, at 1. The EIS was adopted in 2006. New York State’s Empire State Development, Atlantic Yards Draft Environmental Impact Statement (DEIS)—July 18, 2006, http://www.empire.state.ny.us/Subsidiaries_Projects/ Data/AtlanticYards/AdditionalResources/AYDEIS/AYDEIS.html (last visited Mar. 9, 2010). FEIS was adopted on November 27, 2006. New York State’s Empire State Development, Atlantic Yards Final Environmental Impact Statement (FEIS)—Corrected and Amended November 27, 2006, http://www.empire.state.ny.us/Subsidiaries_Projects/Data/AtlanticYards/Addi tionalResources/AYFEIS/AYFEIS.html (last visited Mar. 9, 2010). 177 Only eight community groups joined the CBA coalition, as compared to the more than 50 groups that are opposed to the project. Develop—Don’t Destroy Brooklyn, The Opposition, http://dddb.net/php/opposition.php (last visited Oct. 14, 2009) (listing opposition groups). Testimony made on behalf of Good Jobs New York recognized that “[p]erhaps the most striking is that elsewhere CBAs are negotiated by one broad coalition of groups that would otherwise oppose a project, a coalition that includes labor and community organizations representing a variety of interests . . . . In the BAY [Brooklyn Atlantic Yards] case, several groups, all of which have publicly supported the project already, have each engaged in what seem to be separate negotiations on particular issues.” Public Hearing of the New York City Council Comm. on Econ. Dev. on the Proposed Brooklyn Atlantic Yards Project (May 26, 2005) (comments of Bettina Damiani, Project Dir., Good Jobs New York), available at http://www.goodjobsny.org/testimony_bay_5_05.htm [hereinafter Damiani testimony]; see also Develop—Don’t Destroy Brooklyn, Where is SALKIN REVISED.DOC 200 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY stakeholders excluded, and all of the coalition community groups have received funding from the developer.178 Additionally, some of the most important commitments in the agreement are likely unenforceable.179 For the community groups that were not given a chance to participate in defining the developer’s public responsibilities— and there are many such groups180—the CBA was a wholly the Community in “CBA”?, Apr. 20, 2007, http://www.dddb.net/php/ latestnews_Linked.php?id=696. 178 See, e.g., Damiani testimony, supra note 177, (“The negotiations surrounding the development of the BAY project have been marked by secrecy . . . . Unsurprisingly, this process has contributed to a fragmentation of community responses, as some groups have been able to work with the ‘designated developer’ to advance their concerns while others have not.”); Jess Wisloski, Ratner Invites Chosen Few to Draft Agreement, BROOKLYN PAPER, Oct. 2, 2004, http://www.brooklynpaper.com/stories/27/38/ 27_38nets2.html (discussing the secrecy and exclusivity of CBA negotiations); Norman Oder, Atlantic Yards Process a “Modern Blueprint”? Only if the Times Ignores the Evidence, TIMES RATNER REPORT, Oct. 13, 2005, http://timesratnerreport.blogspot.com/2005/10/atlantic-yards-processmodern.html) (calling the Atlantic Yards and its CBA “a national model in public manipulation and broken promises”); Norman Oder, With $1.5M Grant/Loan, FCR Bails Out National ACORN, Parent of Major CBA Partner, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, Dec. 2, 2008, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot. com/2008/12/with-15m-grantloan-fcr-bails-out.html (reporting that the developer gave one of the CBA signatories a $1.5 million bailout); Norman Oder, AY CBA Witness Bloomberg Blasts CBAs as Extortion; Signatory Nimmons Brushes off Questions from The Local, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, Aug. 26, 2009, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot.com/2009/08/ay-cbawitness-bloomberg-blasts-cbas-as.html (“On July 22, Forest City Ratner executive Mary Anne Gilmartin confirmed at a public meeting that the developer provides funds to all of the signatories of the Community Benefits Agreement.”). 179 See, e.g., Norman Oder, More Criticism of the Atlantic Yards Community Benefits Agreement: It (Mostly) Doesn’t Apply if Ratner Sells the Project, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, Mar. 30, 2009, http://atlanticyardsreport .blogspot.com/2009/03/more-criticism-of-atlantic-yards.html (explaining that many provisions in the CBA would not apply if the developer were to sell the project). Additionally, it is not clear that the CBA, and especially its affordable housing promises, would be enforceable if only the arena were to be built. 180 See, e.g., The Opposition, supra note 177 (listing opposition groups). SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 201 inadequate substitute for the city’s land use review process, even if that process is not ideal for large scale developments.181 As urban planning professor Lance Freeman has explained: While the CBA does at least give some of the most disenfranchised residents an opportunity to reap some benefits from the project . . . there is no mechanism to insure that the “community” in a CBA is representative of the community. If the signatories to the CBA were simply viewed as another interest group, that might be ok. But the CBA is being presented as illustrative of the development’s community input. Public officials are posing for pictures with the developer and signatories to the CBA, giving the impression that the community had significant input into the planning [of] Atlantic Yards. This is not necessarily the case. [T]he CBA . . . cannot be viewed as a substitute for a true planning process that includes community input. If a developer is proposing a project that will unduly burden 181 See, e.g., Norman Oder, Catching Up with Coney Island: How CBAlike Trade-offs May Have Sacrificed the Amusement Area, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, Aug. 7, 2009, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot.com/2009/08/ catching-up-with-coney-island-how-cba.html (noting that the city’s uniform land use review process failed to “resolve opposing views” regarding the Coney Island rezoning); Norman Oder, Flashback, 2005: Roger Green Says AY Area “Not Blighted;” Academic Says AY a Far Cry from Times Square Blight, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, Feb. 19, 2009, http://atlanticyardsreport. blogspot.com/2009/02/flashback-2005-roger-green-says-ay-area.html (quoting state Assemblyman Daniel O’Donnell as calling the city’s planning review process a “horse and pony show” because the city council often ignores the recommendations of local community boards); Norman Oder, HPD Official Says Development Trade-offs Should Be Transparent (and Implicitly Indicts the AY Approval Process), ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, Nov. 7, 2008, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot.com/2008/11/hpd-official-says-development -trade.html (quoting an official from the city Department of Housing Preservation as explaining that “ULURP is awfully late to start a conversation about a large project. It’s one thing if you’re talking about a small project, and you’re going to tweak a floor . . . or affordability, slightly. If you’re talking about a large-scale project, ULURP is simply too late to really have that dialogue”). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 202 the community, exacting benefits in exchange for tolerating these burdens is fine idea. Ideally, this would be done as part of a democratic planning process. When negotiated by private organizations, however, this is symptomatic of a flawed planning process. When CBAs are used in place of an inclusive planning process they run the risk of legitimating the very process they are supposed to counteract, planning and development that disenfranchises.182 Since the Atlantic Yards CBA was signed in 2005, public officials involved in the Atlantic Yards development have admitted that the project should have gone through the local planning process.183 Mayor Bloomberg, who enthusiastically endorsed the CBA in 2005 has now come full circle, stating that he is “violently opposed to community benefits agreements” and that a “small group of people, [who] feather their own nests. . . [and] extort money from the developer” is “just not good government.”184 Even the developer has removed the CBA 182 Freeman, supra note 173 (emphasis added); see also Norman Oder, Push for AY Development Trust Begins; How Much Power Would it Have?, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, June 17, 2008, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot. com/2008/06/push-for-ay-development-trust-begins.html (quoting a city council member as remarking that “[t]he fundamental mistake that was made here, really the original [mistake] of this project, is that it was approved in a way that went around all the usual process[es] for approving a big project . . . . We never had a chance to fix all the problems.”); Norman Oder, ACORN’s Lewis Gets Fiery as “Affordable Housing” Debate Heats Up, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, Mar. 1, 2006, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot. com/2006/03/acorns-lewis-gets-fiery-as-affordable.html (commenting on the controversy that the CBA and the lack of local review has engendered, law professor Vicki Been opined that “[o]ne of the take home messages is we need to use this opportunity to figure out how to fix the [planning] system more broadly so we’re not having these kinds of fights later in the year or decades”). 183 See, e.g., Norman Oder, After Doctoroff Admits AY Should’ve Gone Through ULURP, Will Bloomy, Burden Follow?, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, Dec. 12, 2007, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot.com/2007/12/after-doctor off-admits-ay-shouldve-gone.html. 184 Norman Oder, AY CBA Witness Bloomberg Blasts CBAs as Extortion; Signatory Nimmons Brushes Off Questions from The Local, ATLANTIC YARDS SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 203 from its website,185 which at one point prominently displayed information about the project’s community benefits.186 This CBA experience is used to demonstrate that not all CBAs are “textbook” illustrations of the true benefits of meaningful CBA processes and results. In some cases, it is possible that the CBA framework could provide a viable alternative to more conventional planning techniques. But, as illustrated by this example, such a process is susceptible to capture and manipulation. B. Do CBAs Advance Narrow Interests at the Expense of the Larger Community? While comprehensive land use plans are designed to benefit the community as a whole, and community-based plans are generally intended to be incorporated into more general planning documents, CBAs are negotiated to benefit small neighborhoods within a metropolitan area. Because of their targeted focus, it has occasionally been contended that CBA coalitions divert resources for themselves at the expense of the larger community. When projects covered by CBAs receive significant public subsidies, as they often do, this perception is all the more heightened.187 REPORT, Aug. 26, 2009, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot.com/2009/08/aycba-witness-bloomberg-blasts-cbas-as.html. 185 See Barclay’s Center Brooklyn, http://www.barclayscenter.com (last visited Oct. 14, 2009). 186 The developer, in fact, touted the CBA in many of the project’s promotional materials. See, e.g., Norman Oder, In Seventh Slick Brochure, Forest City Ratner Touts “Historic” CBA, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, Mar. 3, 2008, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot.com/2008/03/in-seventh-slickbrochure-forest-city.html (discussing a brochure calling the CBA “historic”). 187 See Matthew Schuerman, The C.B.A. at Atlantic Yards: But Is It Legal?, N.Y. OBSERVER, Mar. 14, 2006, http://www.observer.com/node/ 34377 (“Carl Weisbrod, the former president of the city Economic Development Corporation, criticized the use of CBA’s in projects that receive public funds—one of which is Atlantic Yards—as fundamentally undemocratic. ‘If the public is putting money into the project and the developer is allocating that money in private deals with the community, it is SALKIN REVISED.DOC 204 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY CBA supporters have made persuasive arguments against this premise, explaining that CBAs can produce social and economic goods that ultimately benefit their surrounding regions. As explained by the Partnership for Working Families, a national organization that promotes CBAs, “Community benefits tools maximize returns on local government investments . . . . Community benefits programs can transform regions through stronger, more equitable economies . . . . The community benefits model works for developers, too . . . . Public input results in better projects that benefit the whole community . . . . Community benefits are part of a smart growth agenda.”188 Indeed, the CBA framework is inherently pro-development, and it can help to obtain project approvals where NIMBYism might otherwise prevail.189 Additionally, CBAs, like development agreements,190 can add a measure of certainty to development projects by setting up mechanisms to resolve community concerns that might arise during buildout, before they ripen into public opposition or litigation.191 As with the question of whether CBAs distort the planning not government setting the priorities. Generally speaking, it is city taxpayer dollars that are being spent in not necessarily high priority areas,’ he said. ‘It shouldn’t be some local community groups making these decisions. It should be a cross-section of the community and city government.’”). 188 THE PARTNERSHIP FOR WORKING FAMILIES, COMMUNITY BENEFITS: PRACTICAL TOOLS FOR PROACTIVE DEVELOPMENT 3, available at http://communitybenefits.org/downloads/CB%20Tools%20for%20Proactive% 20Development.pdf. 189 See, e.g., id. at 3 (“CBA advocates are pro-growth . . . . Once an agreement is achieved, the developer can feel confident that they [sic] have real community support [for] the project, easing the approvals process for everyone.”). 190 See Michael B. Kent, Jr., Forming a Tie That Binds: Development Agreements in Georgia and the Need for Legislative Clarity, 30 ENVIRONS ENVTL. L. & POL’Y J. 1, 8–9 (2006) (explaining how development agreements provide certainty in the land development process). 191 Most CBAs provide for mediation and/or binding arbitration in the case of a dispute between the coalition and the developer. See, e.g., Longfellow CBA, supra note 95, at 24 (mediation); LAX CBA, supra note 95, at 33 (arbitration). SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 205 process and produce counterproductive results, the effect of a CBA on the allocation of metropolitan resources will vary depending on the circumstances surrounding its adoption and the terms that it embraces. A CBA that is negotiated by a historically disempowered community for a development that will have significant negative impacts will advance equity and fairness goals, rather than inhibit them. But other situations can be easily imagined in which CBAs could lead to private windfalls and misallocations of public and private resources. While this has not been a problem in California, the New York CBAs have not demonstrated as much integrity. One situation in which CBAs may lead to windfall benefits occurs when coalition community groups receive a direct financial benefit in exchange for their support of a project. This occurred in relation to the Atlantic Yards CBA, as noted above. The director of the Partnership for Working Families, responding to this situation, stated: “[a]s a matter of principle, groups in our network don’t take money from developers. We want to avoid any appearance of a conflict of interest . . . .”192 Ideals may be important to the community benefits movement, but without conflict of interest regulations to protect the integrity of CBAs, the movement will continue to be susceptible to developer-coalition collusion. It is also possible that communities could demand excessive benefits from developers eager to obtain public support and quick project approvals. While there is nothing unlawful about this in the context of a purely private agreement, especially where the community will suffer definite and negative development impacts, the effect that such a CBA may have on government decision-makers raises ethical and constitutional problems. Ethical considerations come into play where coalitions are used as a proxy for politicians seeking particular community amenities for specific constituent groups. Again, the trouble has 192 Norman Oder, Conflict of Interest? $350K to CBA Signatories Shows Departure From L.A. Model, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, June 8, 2006, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot.com/2006/06/conflict-of-interest-350k-tocba.html. SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 206 been caused by New York CBAs, and similar sorts of agreements even prompted a New York City Bar Association report in 1988. The report unequivocally counseled against permitting CBA-type deals: The ad hoc payment of money or services in return for favorable governmental action also adversely affects the decision-making process. In egregious cases, the decision maker is corrupted. In less egregious cases, satisfying the wish list for a borough president, community board or a mayor enhances the recipient’s political power. The decision-maker may accept the project in order to get the unrelated amenities, when perhaps it should be voted down. Thus integrity is eroded, of the government in general and of the zoning laws and land use regulations in particular.193 These ethical concerns also contribute to the reasoning behind the Supreme Court’s doctrine prohibiting development exactions,194 which “has its roots in the allegations of coercion and illicit motive that long have animated judicial and academic debate about exactions and more generally, about the unconstitutional conditions doctrine.”195 Development agreements permit local governments to avoid the exactions ban by negotiating for developer concessions, usually traded for a guarantee that zoning and land use regulations will not be changed in a manner that prevents successive phases of a project. Because these agreements are voluntary, development approvals are not considered to be conditioned on the provision of development amenities, even if this is the de facto (and often 196 desired) result. Local governments are currently authorized to 193 Matthew Schuerman, C.B.A.’s: Coming to a Bar Near You, N.Y. OBSERVER, Jan. 13, 2006, http://www.observer.com/node/34098. 194 See Dolan v. City of Tigard, 512 U.S. 374 (1994); Nollan v. Cal. Coastal Comm’n, 483 U.S. 825 (1987). 195 Vicki Been, “Exit” as a Constraint on Land Use Exactions: Rethinking the Unconstitutional Conditions Doctrine, 91 COLUM. L. REV. 473, 475 (1991). 196 See generally Callies & Tappendorf, supra note 85. SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 207 enter into development agreements in about a dozen states, but such arrangements have also been upheld in states where no statutory authority for development agreements exists, as in Texas and Massachusetts.197 In some states where development agreements have not been approved, either by statute or judicial fiat, the development process is often dominated by other types of negotiated agreements between developers and planning entities, often resulting from environmental mitigation measures where local environmental review occurs. The problem with unauthorized and unregulated bilateral government-developer negotiations is that they open up the possibility that “‘needy’ cities and towns [may] see their zoning powers as for sale to the highest bidder.”198 And where this is the case, short term economic goals may be just as likely to motivate local government decision makers as are the types of social and environmental policies that require foresight and longterm planning.199 In the states that have enacted development agreement statutes, on the other hand, the comprehensive plan acts as a safeguard to ensure that development agreements further the community’s broad goals and policies for future development.200 States such as California, which require consistency between zoning and the comprehensive plan, also require consistency in the negotiation of development agreements. The development agreement framework has also allowed planning agencies, community organizations and 197 See Curtin & Witten, supra note 24, at 340, 338–39 (discussing recent Massachusetts cases that “conclude that a promise by a petitioner is different from a requirement imposed as a condition precedent by the municipality”); Kent, Jr., supra note 190, at 6, n.25 (2006) (citing cases permitting development agreements in the absence of enabling legislation from Alabama, Nebraska, and New Mexico). 198 See Curtin & Witten, supra note 24, at 338. 199 See Camacho II, supra note 54, at 271 (“While modern bilateral negotiation attempts to address some of the intrinsic inefficiencies of the traditional command and control approach . . . bilateral negotiation approaches promote adversarial and self-interested behavior while ignoring the long-term community engagement that is essential to the legitimacy of local decision-making processes.”). 200 Curtin & Witten, supra note 24, at 345. SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 208 developers to work together in building CBAs, while in other states local governments have struggled to determine where they fit into the CBA process. Four New York CBAs have been negotiated to date, relating to Atlantic Yards, the Gateway Center at Bronx Terminal Market, Yankee Stadium, and the expansion of Columbia University.201 In each of these cases, the lack of strong and inclusive community coalitions and the amount of influence wielded by public officials suggests that there were, at the very least, opportunities for this sort of bargaining away of the city’s comprehensive planning goals.202 201 See Salkin & Lavine, supra note 83, at 308–17. Atlantic Yards continues to be promoted with much zeal by the Empire State Development Corporation, even though its public benefits have decreased substantially since the project was approved in 2006. Frank Gehry is no longer the architect, for example; the project’s affordable housing component has been significantly delayed; and a renegotiated land deal with the Metropolitan Transportation Authority has resulted in an arguably less valuable package for the authority (and for New York City subway riders). In May 2009, the New York City Independent Budget Office (“IBO”) concluded that changes in the project’s commercial component and increased subsidies rendered the arena a net money loser for the city. See Norman Oder, Senate Hearing: No Tough Questions for ESDC, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, May 29, 2009, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot.com/2009/05/senate-hearing-no-tou gh-questions-for.html. Despite this revelation, and despite increasingly loud calls for more transparency in the project, the Empire State Development Corporation refuses to release its updated cost-benefit analysis until after the project’s next board approval. As a result, the public will not get a chance to comment on the situation. What’s more, while refusing to provide a meaningful response to serious allegations that the project may no longer be in the public’s best interest, ESDC has “not looked closely at that [the IBO’s] report.” Norman Oder, ESDC, FCR Face, Answer, Evade Tough Questions, ATLANTIC YARDS REPORT, July 23, 2009, http://atlanticyardsreport.blogspot. com/2009/07/esdc-fcr-face-answer-evade-tough.html. In the Bronx, it was revealed last year that the mayor’s office had pressured the Yankees to provide a free luxury suite for the mayor and other high-ranking officials. State Senator Richard Brodsky, who has been urging reforms, asked “what is the public interest here and who’s protecting it?” David W. Chen, City Pressed for Use of Yankee Luxury Suite, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 30, 2008, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2008/11/30/nyregion/ 30stadium.html. The project has been riddled with other controversies, from 202 SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 209 In states that do not allow development agreements, the exactions issue also raises the question of the most appropriate way for public officials to react when faced with a developer that refuses to negotiate a CBA with a strong and broadly inclusive CBA coalition: the local official can become involved in CBA negotiations and try to persuade the developer into negotiating, which might raise exactions problems if that persuasion amounts to coercion; or she can remain on the sidelines and hope that the parties reach a deal. In Pittsburgh, the mayor and county executive became very involved in negotiations for the Penguins CBA, to the point where they committed $1 million in matching funds to help secure a grocery store and YMCA for the community. Both of these facilities are sorely needed in the underserved community located near the arena site, and the CBA coalition was one of the largest and most inclusive coalitions formed to date. In short, this was an ideal situation for the negotiation of a CBA. But the city has changed its tune toward CBAs since its legal department concluded that “[w]hile [CBAs] could provide benefits to the community, they are simply not a part of what the Planning Commission may consider when reviewing master-development plans and project-development plans.”203 a U.S. Congressional inquiry to its tax-exempt bonding scheme (which resulted in an IRS move to close certain loopholes), to an 18-month delay in implementing the CBA. With the old Yankee Stadium still standing after 311 days, preventing the construction of parks to replace the ones covered over by the new stadium, some people have begun referring to the “Yankee Stadium Death Watch.” Neil deMause, Yankee Stadium Death Watch: Day 331, N.Y. NEWS BLOG, http://blogs.villagevoice.com/runninscared/archives/ 2009/08/yankee_stadium_3.php. With problems such as these it seems fair to inquire into the propriety of the CBA, which was completed with no community participation and which is very likely unenforceable. The Gateway Center at Bronx Terminal Market and the Columbia University expansion have both raised controversies of their own, but their CBAs have received less criticism. 203 Chris Togneri, Updated North Shore Plan Approved, PITTSBURG TRIBUNE REV., June 10, 2009, http://pittsburghlive.com/x/pittsburghtrib/ news/pittsburgh/s_628882.html. See also Oro Valley Town Council Minutes, Regular Session, Aug. 27, 2008 (“Town Attorney Tobin Rosen explained that SALKIN REVISED.DOC 210 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY C. How Should a Local Government Respond if a CBA is Inconsistent with the Comprehensive Plan? To the extent that CBAs cover land use and community development issues, they may produce a different vision for the neighborhood than the vision articulated in a legally adopted comprehensive plan covering the entire community. A recent example from the Bronx highlights how CBA provisions can conflict with government planning efforts in this manner. The Kingsbridge Armory Redevelopment Alliance (“KARA”), the first truly inclusive grassroots CBA coalition in New York City, raised this problem in the summer of 2009 when, during negotiations, it demanded a ban on new grocery stores in the development. To some community members, the provision was intended to protect existing businesses and the jobs they provided; but to others, the ban was viewed as interfering with the community’s need for grocery stores with more healthy and organic food.204 For the redevelopment project to proceed, the 205 site will need to be rezoned to C4-4 —a general commercial designation consistent with the comprehensive plan206 that typically permits grocery and other retail food stores.207 Accordingly, the CBA poses the question of whether local groups should be able to modify generally applicable zoning these agreements are great if neighbors and developers are willing to agree to it. He pointed out that the Town cannot require the agreement if the developer meets the requirements of the Zoning Code.”). 204 Terry Pristin, Proposed Supermarket Divides Bronx Community, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 29, 2009, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/30/ realestate/commercial/30armory.html?_r=1. 205 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE SHOPS AT THE ARMORY PROJECT Fig. S-4, http://www.nyc.gov/html/oec/downloads/pdf/08DME004X/08DME004 X_FEIS/08DME004X_FEIS_00_Executive_Summary.pdf (last visited Dec. 1, 2009). 206 The Kingsbridge Armory Redevelopment Alliance Proposal Fig. S-4, S-6, http://www.nyc.gov/html/oec/downloads/pdf/08DME004X/08DME004X _FEIS/08DME004X_FEIS_00_Executive_Summary.pdf (last visited Dec. 1, 2009). 207 NEW YORK CITY PLANNING COMMISSION, ZONING RESOLUTION 534 (2009), available at http://www.nyc.gov/html/dcp/pdf/zone/allarticles.pdf. SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 211 regulations via private agreement, even if the city has specifically decided to apply those general regulations to the site. Although in many cases this type of use restriction would resemble a simple restrictive covenant, the city in the Kingsbridge case must implicitly approve any CBA related to the development because of the extensive subsidies being given to the developer.208 Can the city with one hand apply a uniform, general regulation, and with the other approve a private pact limiting the reach of the general law? Another hypothetical could be imagined where a comprehensive plan and implementing land use regulation articulates a preference for recreational facilities in designated areas, but such facilities are not planned for a neighborhood where a coalition has just negotiated a private CBA to include a neighborhood park. Such a CBA could be viewed as inconsistent with the comprehensive plan, raising the question of who speaks for the neighborhood. A core principle of the social justice movement is that the community speaks for itself. What then, is the appropriate role of the government? If in fact the community coalition is representative of the views of the neighborhood it purports to represent, and where the neighborhood, speaking through its coalition representatives expresses the desire for a certain amenity that is inconsistent with the comprehensive plan, whether the coalition and the project sponsor should legally agree to the amenity may be an open question. Going back to the notion that the local government is responsible for the development, adoption and implementation of the comprehensive plan, where a CBA contains items that are inconsistent with that plan, should the locality view the CBA as public input and begin a process to amend the plan and regulations to make them consistent with such views? Or should the government refuse to amend the comprehensive plan, thereby preventing the project 208 See, e.g., Ivonne Salazar, Live Blogging From Armory IDA Hearing: Tax Breaks Approved, Land Use Review to Begin, BRONX NEWS NETWORK, Mar. 11, 2009, http://www.bronxnewsnetwork.org/2009/03/live-bloggingfrom-armory-ida-hearing_11.html (discussing the last phase of the project going through the city’s land use review process). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 212 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY sponsor from fulfilling its promises? This is a critical question for all private parties involved in the negotiation of a CBA. Legally binding CBAs arguably should not be entered into where one party lacks the legal ability to deliver on a promise, given that such situations are susceptible to manipulation and bad faith. Across the country there is a wide disparity as to the level of government involvement in the development and “acceptance” of CBAs as a condition of development approval. As noted above, local governments in California are likely to be at least tangentially involved in CBA negotiations. In these cases, the government’s involvement may lead to information for the parties indicating that land use related terms of the CBA may not be enforceable absent an adjustment to current planning documents and regulations. In states such as New York, where the government is not involved in purely private CBA negotiations, or at least is better advised not to be, the municipality must decide how, if at all, it should embrace the community coalition’s articulated desires for certain community amenities that are not currently part of the land use regulatory regime. At a minimum, the planning department within the municipality will be on notice that the needs of certain sections of the community are not being met by the overall plan and vision for the community as a whole. This information should be the basis for a re-evaluation of the comprehensive plan—either specific aspects of the plan or the plan as a whole—to make sure that the plan and its implementing regulations are serving the best interests of the jurisdiction as a whole. Nevertheless, as explained above, conditioning project approvals on criteria not included in the zoning ordinances or comprehensive plan may, if coercive enough, make the action unlawful. Further support for the notion that CBAs should inform and influence the comprehensive planning process, which should be ongoing and continuously evolving, is that the methodology used for the development of a CBA tends to be more inclusive than that used for the development of a comprehensive plan, at least where no community-based planning programs exist. The protocols used in coalition building for the purposes of SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 213 negotiating a CBA, including the consensus building process for articulating community desires, are more empowering than the typical opportunities for public participation in the development and implementation of a comprehensive plan. While it can be argued that local governments give up planning authority by yielding to the community desires expressed in CBAs that are inconsistent with the existing plan, it may be better viewed as the government doing exactly what it is supposed to be doing—viewing the planning process as ongoing and engaging public involvement. V. CONCLUSIONS When CBAs are negotiated by broad based, inclusive coalitions that are truly representative of community interests, and such agreements result in a community planning vision that dramatically differs from the existing traditional comprehensive plan and implementing regulations for the area, it indicates that existing governmental planning processes may be inadequate, and the most appropriate action for a local government to take 209 may be to reform the way that it plans. As described above, a new paradigm of community-based planning and environmental justice has emerged that places an increased focus on 209 See Oro Valley Town Council Minutes, Regular Session, Aug. 27, 2008, available at http://lexicon.orovalleyaz.gov/ACK/ArchiveSearch/ ArchiveSearch.htm (select Option 2; search minutes; enter date 08/27/08; select study session) (“Bill Adler, Town resident and member of the Planning & Zoning Commission presented information about Community Benefit Agreements. He explained that the current process of meeting with neighborhoods and developers could be formalized, bridging communication between neighbors, the Town and developers. He explained the importance of citizens first meeting without the applicant so they can be educated on the development review process, Zoning Code and entitlements and where effect of change can take place on the development so that they have an understanding of the process before meeting with the developer. Terry Parish, Town resident, encouraged the Council to formalize the process so that developers know upfront that the goal is to come to an agreement with neighbors and require neighbors to be educated on the development process.”). SALKIN REVISED.DOC 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 214 transparency, accountability, and meaningful public participation, within the existing planning process. As explained by law professor Alejandro Esteban Camacho, there are four underlying reasons for developing more participatory planning models: (1) that an open negotiation process can thwart the corruption and unfair dealing so closely associated with conventional negotiated land use regulation; (2) that participatory processes are necessary to obtain important information about the interests and preferences of affected parties; (3) that fostering meaningful participation has a positive impact on both participants’ and the general public’s satisfaction with the regulatory process and outcomes; and (4) that direct participation serves the important goal of enhancing accountability for governmental services and decisions.210 In California, local governments have responded to CBA campaigns by working closely with community groups and consistently incorporating CBAs into development agreements. The result, more often than not, has been an improved planning process for all parties. In New York and the many other states where development agreements have not been formally authorized, either by statute or judicial order, the CBA model is less ideal for fostering this type of collaboration. Other ways must be found to educate the public about the development process and make it more transparent, democratic and accountable. Fortunately, local governments and planning commissions already have the tools to improve the way that planning decisions are made. To list just a few methods to encourage community-based planning, local governments can: (1) make planning information easily accessible online and at designated public facilities in all communities and neighborhoods; (2) provide hearing notices that are actually designed to 210 Camacho II, supra note 54, at 279. SALKIN REVISED.DOC COMMUNITY BENEFITS AGREEMENTS 4/27/2010 8:24 PM 215 reach impacted community members, rather than the “rudimentary public notice”211 mandated by state or local law; (3) hold hearings in locations close to impacted neighborhoods and at times of day when community members are likely to be available; (4) hold additional public meetings, workshops, and other events in order to reach a diverse cross section of community members; (5) partner with existing neighborhood associations, civic organizations, and faith based entities which typically have established community networks; (6) make clear that planners will be responsive to neighborhood residents’ concerns and desires regarding future growth; and (7) express a commitment to ensure that communitybased planning is an integral part of the planning process and will, to the greatest extent practical, be incorporated into the comprehensive plan. Development controversies can also be headed off by including the community in discussions about proposed projects early enough in the process so that impacted stakeholders can help to shape project plans. Too often, communities do not get a chance to participate in the planning process until the developer has already worked out its financials and the local government has invested substantial resources in preliminary planning reviews, making it likely that the project’s fate has already been decided. The CBA movement has clearly demonstrated the importance of having a system in place whereby community members can feel that they play an important role not just in the planning process, but also in the development review process. Especially in those states that do not permit development agreements, leaving community involvement unregulated in the hands of private developers carries substantial risks that the CBA concept will be co-opted, abused, or ignored. Recognizing 211 Id. at 279–80. SALKIN REVISED.DOC 216 4/27/2010 8:24 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY this, local governments, as part of comprehensive planning function, should developing alternative planning processes community benefits movement’s goals democracy, and accountability. their continuous be proactive in that advance the of inclusiveness, STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM THE FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC AND THE FUTURE OF GOVERNMENT SUPPORT FOR THE HOUSING FINANCE SYSTEM Thomas H. Stanton* In devising the government’s response to the Great Depression, President Franklin Roosevelt turned not only to bankers, economists and lawyers, but also to scholars and practitioners in the field of public administration such as Charles Merriam and Louis Brownlow.1 This article seeks to build on that tradition. While other disciplines concern themselves with devising appropriate policies, public administration focuses more on trying to ensure that those policies are effectively implemented. Lessons from public administration, and especially the art of organizational design, provide insight about the failure of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and also suggest more stable means for government to support today’s troubled housing finance system. *Thomas H. Stanton is a Fellow of the Center for the Study of American Government at Johns Hopkins University. He is a member of the board of directors of the National Academy of Public Administration and a former member of the federal Senior Executive Service. His publications include two books on government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) and two edited books on federal organization and management. Concerns expressed in A State of Risk: Will Government Sponsored Enterprises be the next Financial Crisis? (HarperCollins, 1991) helped lead to the enactment of several pieces of legislation and the creation of a new GSE regulator, the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO). Mr. Stanton’s B.A. degree is from the University of California at Davis, M.A. from Yale University, and J.D. from the Harvard Law School. 1 See, e.g., PERI E. ARNOLD, MAKING THE MANAGERIAL PRESIDENCY: COMPREHENSIVE REORGANIZATION PLANNING, 1905–1996, at 81–117 (1998). 217 STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 218 Part I of this Article outlines how the two companies failed as a result of high leverage, poor business decisions, and weak regulatory supervision. Part II describes inherent vulnerabilities of the government-sponsored enterprise (GSE) as an organizational form. Specifically, GSE officers and directors have a legal obligation to serve shareholders and this can conflict with pressure from other stakeholders to serve the public purposes for which the GSE is chartered. Often this tension is manageable but at key times it is not. The GSE uses its government backing to gain so much power as to dominate virtually any system of financial accountability that government might try to establish. Part III evaluates the GSE as an organizational form. While the GSE may possess greater capacity and flexibility than a wholly owned government corporation or other government agency, it is subject to only limited accountability and displays significant vulnerabilities as it evolves over its organizational life-cycle. Part IV recommends that the two GSEs be placed into receivership and converted into wholly owned government corporations. The article concludes that the two government corporations should either be terminated after five years or, if policymakers believe that there is yet further value to be gained from them at that time, that they be organized into a single government corporation and reauthorized on a five-year cycle to periodically determine whether their public benefits still outweigh their public costs. Caution is merited here because of the systemic implications of concentrating so much financial risk into a single specialized financial institution, whether in the public or private sector. I. WHY FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC FAILED On September 7, 2008, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac voluntarily went into conservatorship.2 As they recognize their 2 See, e.g., 12 U.S.C. § 4617 (2008) (prescribing the terms of conservatorship of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac through the Federal Housing Enterprise Safety and Soundness Act of 1992); James B. Lockhart, Dir., Fed. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 219 losses it becomes clear that taxpayer costs from the government backing of the two companies will be substantial.3 The two companies are government-sponsored enterprises, privately owned companies that, before their failure, benefitted from the perception that the government would back their debt obligations and mortgage-backed securities (MBSs).4 There are Hous. Fin. Agency, Statement of FHFA Director James B. Lockhart (Sept. 7, 2008), http://money.cnn.com/2008/09/07/news/economy/lockhart_ statement/index.htm (“In order to restore balance between safety and soundness and mission, FHFA has placed Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into conservatorship.”); Henry M. Paulson, Jr., Sec’y, Treasury Department, Statement on Treasury and Federal Housing Finance Agency Action to Protect Financial Markets and Taxpayers (Sept. 7, 2008), http://www.ustreas.gov/press/releases/hp1129.htm (“I support the Director’s decision as necessary and appropriate and had advised him that conservatorship was the only form in which I would commit taxpayer dollars to the GSEs.”). The law prescribes that the regulator should use conservatorship to restore the companies to financial health. See, e.g., FED. HOUS. FIN. AGENCY, FACT SHEET: QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS ON CONSERVATORSHIP 2 (2008) (“A conservatorship is the legal process in which a person or entity is appointed to establish control and oversight over a Company to put it in a sound and solvent condition. In a conservatorship, the powers of the Company’s directors, officers, and shareholders are transferred to the designated Conservator.”). 3 See Dawn Kopecki, Fannie, Freddie Won’t Repay All Aid, Lockhart Says, BLOOMBERG, July 30, 2009, http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/ news?pid=20601103&sid=aEwoLtQMHq5Y (“Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the largest U.S. mortgage-finance companies, won’t be able to repay all of the $84.9 billion in federal aid they have received since being seized by the government last year, their regulator said.”). 4 More formally, a government-sponsored enterprise is a government chartered, privately owned and privately controlled institution that, while lacking an express government guarantee, benefits from the perception that the government stands behind its financial obligations. See Ronald C. Moe & Thomas H. Stanton, Government Sponsored Enterprises as Federal Instrumentalities: Reconciling Private Management with Public Accountability, 49 PUB. ADMIN. REV. 321, 321–22 (1989); accord 2 U.S.C. § 622(8) (2009) (definition Congress enacted in amendments to the Congressional Budget Act of 1974). The Treasury purchase of stock in Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac on September 7, 2008, and its commitment to infuse up to $200 billion into the companies as needed, made the government’s backing explicit rather than implicit, as it had been before the STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 220 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY five GSEs: Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, the Federal Home Loan Bank System, the Farm Credit System and a small GSE known as Farmer Mac.5 Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and Farmer Mac are investor-owned. The Farm Credit System and Federal Home Loan Bank System are cooperatives, owned by their memberborrowers.6 A sixth GSE, Sallie Mae, which funds student loans, gave up its government sponsorship and became a completely private investor-owned company.7 The housing bubble was an unprecedented increase in housing prices averaging over 100 percent from 2000–2006 in urban areas, followed by a substantial drop in prices.8 The failure of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac cannot be attributed solely to the housing credit bubble and collapse. Rather, it appears that the collapse of the housing credit bubble was a precipitating event with consequences that could have been avoided by more prudent practices by the two GSEs and their management, and that revealed shortcomings in the GSE as an institutional form. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac committed serious misjudgments that helped to bring about their insolvency. The most serious misjudgments involved the companies’ resistance to accepting more effective supervision and capital standards.9 For companies went into government hands. 5 THOMAS H. STANTON, GOVERNMENT-SPONSORED ENTERPRISES: MERCANTILIST COMPANIES IN THE MODERN WORLD 1 (2002) [hereinafter STANTON, MERCANTILIST COMPANIES]. 6 Thomas H. Stanton, Government-Sponsored Enterprises: Reality Catches up to Public Administration Theory, 69 PUB. ADMIN. REV 632, 632 (2009) [hereinafter Stanton, Public Adminstration Theory]. 7 Thomas H. Stanton, Reducing Government Involvement in a Market: Lessons from the Privatization of Sallie Mae, 28 PUB. BUDGETING. & FIN. 101–23 (2008) [hereinafter Stanton, Reducing Government Involvement]. 8 See, e.g., MARK ZANDI, FINANCIAL SHOCK: A 360º LOOK AT THE SUBPRIME MORTGAGE IMPLOSION, AND HOW TO AVOID THE NEXT FINANCIAL CRISIS (2009). 9 Among the bills that the GSEs helped to defeat in the years 2000–2007 were Fed. Hous. Enterprise Regulatory Reform Act, S. 1100, 110th Cong. (2007) (enacted); Fed. Hous. Fin. Reform Act, H.R. 1427, 110th Cong. (2007) (enacted); Fed. Hous. Fin. Reform Act, 109th Cong. (2005) STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 221 years, starting with their successful efforts to weaken the legislation that established their regulator, the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO),10 the two companies managed to fend off capital standards that would have reduced their excessive leverage and provided a cushion to absorb potential losses.11 In 2007 Freddie Mac concluded a stock buyback program that further weakened the company’s ability to withstand a financial shock.12 As late as March 2008, Freddie (enacted); Fed. Hous. Enterprise Regulatory Reform Act, S. 190, 109th Cong. (2005); Fed. Hous. Enterprise Oversight Modernization Act, S. 1656, 108th Cong. (2003); Leave No Securities Behind Act, H.R. 2022, 108th Cong. (2003); Secondary Mortgage Market Enterprises Regulatory Improvement Act, H.R. 2575, 108th Cong. (2003); Hous. Fin. Regulatory Restructuring Act, H.R. 2803, 107th Cong. (2002); Secondary Mortgage Market Enterprises Regulatory Improvement Act, H.R. 1409, 107th Cong. (2001); Hous. Fin. Regulatory Improvement Act, H.R. 3703, 106th Cong. (2000). 10 Many reports document the successful efforts of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac at weakening the legislation creating OFHEO and prescribing their capital standards. See, e.g., Kenneth H. Bacon, Privileged Position: Fannie Mae Expected to Escape Attempt at Tighter Regulation, WALL ST. J., June 19, 1992, at A1; Stephen Labaton, Power of the Mortgage Twins: Fannie and Freddie Guard Autonomy, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 12 1991, at D1; Carol Matlack, Getting Their Way, NAT’L L.J., Oct. 27, 1990, at 2584–88; Jill Zuckman, Bills to Increase GSE Oversight Move Ahead in House, Senate, CQ WEEKLY, Aug. 3, 1991, http://www.cq.com/display.do?dockey=/ cqonline/prod/data/docs/html/weeklyreport/102/wr404032.html@allnewsarchi ve&metapub=CQ-WEEKLYREPORT&searchIndex=5&seqNum=6. 11 See, e.g., Ben S. Bernanke, Chairman, Bd. of Governors of Fed. Reserve Sys., Address at the UC Berkley/UCLA Symposium: The Future of Mortgage Finance in the U.S. (Oct. 31, 2008) (“For example, the GSEs were reluctant earlier this year to raise capital and to expand their operations, even though this would have helped financial and macroeconomic stability at a time of much-reduced mortgage availability. The GSEs’ disinclination to support the mortgage market was motivated by the fact that raising additional capital would have diluted the values of the holding of the existing private shareholders.”). 12 FREDDIE MAC, 2007 ANN. REP. at 25 (“On March 23, 2007, we announced that our board of directors had authorized us to repurchase up to $1 billion of outstanding shares of common stock. The repurchase program was completed in August 2007.”). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 222 Mac defied calls to increase its capital cushion.13 As late as summer 2008, Fannie Mae continued to resist legislation that would give a federal regulator the discretion to set higher capital standards.14 As a result the two companies were far too weak financially to cope with any significant financial stress that might occur. The companies fought for high leverage because it benefited their shareholders and managers, at least until the companies failed.15 Freddie Mac reported returns on equity of over 20 percent in most years since becoming an investor-owned company in 1989, reaching highs of 47.2 percent in 2002 and 39.0 percent in 2000.16 Fannie Mae reported earnings of almost 17 as much, reaching a high of 39.8 percent in 2001. The two companies fought higher capital requirements because more capital would have diluted those returns to shareholders.18 Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac compounded the problem of their self-inflicted structural vulnerabilities with a series of misjudgments that involved taking on excessive risk just at the 19 point that housing prices were peaking. According to press reports, the chief executives of both Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac disregarded warnings from their risk officers and greatly increased their purchases of risky loans to catch up with the 13 David S. Hilzenrath, Chief Says Freddie Won’t Raise Capital: Mortgage Financer Cites Responsibility to Shareholders, Won’t Increase Loan Capacity, WASH. POST, Mar. 13, 2008, at D04. 14 Steven Sloan, Fannie CEO Details Issues with GSE Bill, AM. BANKER, June 5, 2008, http://www.americanbanker.com/issues/173_109/-3544971.html. 15 Bernanke, supra note 11. 16 FED. HOUS. AGENCY, REPORT TO CONGRESS 110, 127 (2008) (Freddie Mac). 17 Id. at 127. 18 See supra notes 9–11. 19 See James B. Lockhart, Dir., Fed. Hous. Fin. Agency, FHFA’S First Anniversary and Challenges Ahead (July 30, 2009) (transcript available in the National Press Club) (“Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac did not create the housing price bubble, but their procyclical actions further inflated the bubble, despite our regulatory efforts to curtail their growth.”). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 223 market.20 The following excerpts from their annual reports indicate that the two GSEs took on substantial risk from purchasing subprime mortgages (i.e., those with borrowers who failed to meet traditional standards of creditworthiness), “Alt-A” mortgages (i.e., “Alternative-A” mortgages which lacked verification of crucial data about creditworthiness such as the borrower’s income), “interest-only” mortgages (those that permitted borrowers to continue to accrue mortgage principal without paying it down in a timely fashion), and adjustable rate mortgages (ARMs) (those that allowed mortgage interest rates and borrowers’ required monthly payments to increase over time according to a stated index even though the borrower might have qualified only to make monthly payments on the mortgage at a lower interest rate).21 Freddie Mac reported in its 2007 Annual Report that: [t]he proportion of higher risk mortgage loans that were originated in the market during the last four years increased significantly. We have increased our securitization volume of non-traditional mortgage products, such as interest-only loans and loans originated with less documentation in the last two years in response to the prevalence of these products within the origination market. Total non-traditional mortgage products, including those designated as Alt-A and interest-only loans, made up approximately 30% and 24% of our single-family mortgage purchase volume in the years 20 See., e.g., Charles Duhigg, The Reckoning: Pressured to Take More Risk, Fannie Reached Tipping Point, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 5, 2008, http://www.nytimes.com/2008/10/05/business/05fannie.html; Charles Duhigg, At Freddie Mac, Chief Discarded Warning Signs, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 5, 2008, http://www.nytimes.com/2008/08/05/business/05freddie.html; David S. Hilzenrath, Fannie’s Perilous Pursuit of Subprime Loans: As It Tried to Increase Its Business, Company Gave Risks Short Shrift, Documents Show, WASH. POST, Aug. 19, 2008, at D01. 21 Among the most financially risky ARMs were those with initial low rates (so-called “teaser rates”) that reset to much higher rates after two or three years. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 224 ended December 31, 2007 and 2006, respectively.22 Fannie Mae’s 2007 Annual Report states: [w]e are experiencing high serious delinquency rates and credit losses across our conventional single-family mortgage credit book of business, especially for loans to borrowers with low credit scores and loans with high loan-to-value (“LTV”) ratios. In addition, in 2007 we experienced particularly rapid increases in serious delinquency rates and credit losses in some higher risk loan categories, such as Alt-A loans, adjustable-rate loans, interest-only loans, negative amortization loans, loans made for the purchase of condominiums and loans with second liens. Many of these higher risk loans were originated in 2006 and the first half of 2007.23 Fannie Mae reported that purchases of interest-only and negative amortizing ARMs amounted to 7% of its business volume in 2007 and 12% in both 2006 and 2005.24 Moreover, Alt-A mortgage loans “represented approximately 16% of . . . single-family business volume in 2007, compared with approximately 22% and 16% in 2006 and 2005, respectively.”25 Both companies also invested in highly rated private-label, mortgage-related securities, backed by Alt-A or subprime mortgage loans, amounting to total holdings by the two companies of over $200 billion in 2007.26 In short, the mix of private incentives and government backing created a dynamic leading not only to the hubris that brought about the meltdown of internal controls at both Fannie 27 Mae and Freddie Mac a few years ago, but also to their 22 FREDDIE MAC, 2007 ANN. REP., at 13. FANNIE MAE, 2007 ANN. REP., at 24. 24 Id. at 128. 25 Id. at 129. 26 FANNIE MAE, 2007 ANN. REP. 93 (2008); FREDDIE MAC, 2007 ANN. REP. 94 (2008). 27 Thomas H. Stanton, The Life Cycle of the Government-Sponsored Enterprise: Lessons for Design and Accountability, 67 PUB. ADMIN. REV. 837, 840 [hereinafter Stanton, Lessons for Design and Accountability] (2007). 23 STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 225 insolvency in 2008. That said, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac did not cause the housing bubble or the proliferation of subprime and other mortgages that borrowers could not afford to repay. In analyzing the dynamics of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, I discovered a phenomenon that can be called Stanton’s Law: risk will migrate to the place where government is least equipped to deal with it.28 Thus, the capital markets arbitraged across regulatory requirements and sent literally trillions of dollars of mortgages to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac,29 where capital requirements were low and federal supervision was weak.30 However, the capital markets also found other places where government could not manage the risk,31 including structured investment vehicles of commercial banks, private securitization conduits, and collateralized debt obligations that were virtually unregulated except by the vagaries of the rating agencies and exuberance of the market during the housing bubble.32 Huge 28 I first presented this dynamic in 1989 testimony before the Senate Banking Committee, where I pointed out that increases in stringency of capital requirements and government supervision for thrift institutions after the savings and loan debacle would drive many billions of dollars of mortgages from the portfolios of savings and loan associations to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac because their capital standards and government oversight were much weaker. The Safety and Soundness of Government Sponsored Enterprises: Hearing Before the S. Comm. on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, 101st Cong. 41, 52 (1989) (statement of Thomas H. Stanton, Attorney at Law). 29 See, e.g., Report to Congress 2008, supra note 16, at 111 tbl.4 (Fannie Mae), 128 tbl.11 (Freddie Mac) for the annual growth of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. 30 See supra notes 9–11. 31 See, e.g., Ben S. Bernanke, Chairman, Bd. of Governors of Fed. Reserve Sys., Address at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Conference on Bank Structure and Competition: Lessons of the Financial Crisis for Banking Supervision (May 7, 2009). 32 See, e.g., Markus Brunnermeier et al., The Fundamental Principles of Financial Regulation, Geneva Reports on the World Economy 11, Preliminary Conference Draft, Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), Jan. 2009, app. A “The Boundary Problem in Financial Regulation,” at 63–69. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 226 volumes of subprime, Alt-A, interest-only and other “toxic mortgages” went to these parts of the market.33 As the bubble reached its limits and began to deflate, the GSEs tried to catch up and regain the market share that they had lost to the new competition. Former Freddie Mac CEO Richard Syron explained the pressures on the GSEs: The subprime market was developed largely by private label participants, as were most non-traditional mortgage products. Freddie Mac entered the non-traditional slice of the market because, as the private lending sector shifted toward those types of loans, Freddie needed to participate in order to carry out its public mission of promoting affordability, liquidity and stability in housing finance. In addition, if it had not done so, it could not have remained competitive or even relevant in the residential mortgage market we were designed to serve.34 II. LESSONS FROM THE FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC Many other kinds of financial institutions have failed in the current debacle, including commercial banks, thrift institutions, mortgage companies, and insurance companies. Among all of these, the GSE has specific shortcomings that call the value of this institutional form into doubt. In making their mistakes, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac revealed the inherent vulnerabilities of the GSE as an organizational model. First, the GSE lives or dies according to its charter and other laws that determine the conditions under 35 which it operates. That means that GSEs must balance their 33 Id. The Role of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in the Financial Crisis: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Oversight & Government Reform, 110th Cong. 17–22 (2008) [hereinafter Syron Statement] (statement of Richard F. Syron, Former CEO of Freddie Mac), available at http://oversight.house. gov/story.asp?ID=2252. 35 See, e.g., FANNIE MAE, 2007 ANN. REP., at 29–31 (“As a federally chartered corporation, we are subject to the limitations imposed by the 34 STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 227 profit goals against public purposes and those interests of stakeholders which can influence their charters. Second, the GSE combines private ownership with government backing in a way that creates a political force that can dominate virtually any safety-and-soundness framework. GSEs select chief officers, in good part, based on their ability to manage political risk,36 rather than on their ability to manage two of the largest financial institutions in the world. This article will consider these issues in turn. A. GSEs Are Inherently Difficult if Not Impossible to Manage The GSE business model, involving private ownership and public purposes, is difficult, if not impossible, to manage. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were more vulnerable than commercial banks or other federal instrumentalities to the contradictions between the requirement to serve private shareholders and the need to serve public purposes that other stakeholders, including members of Congress, guarded and Charter Act, extensive regulation, supervision and examination by OFHEO and HUD, and regulation by other federal agencies, including the Department of the Treasury and the SEC. We are also subject to many laws and regulations that affect our business, including those regarding taxation and privacy. In addition, the policy, approach or regulatory philosophy of these agencies can materially affect our business.”). 36 For example, in the mid-1990s the Congressional Budget Office reported on some of Fannie Mae’s activities: In keeping with its fiduciary responsibility to shareholders and its own financial interests, the management of the housing GSEs has devoted a significant (but undisclosed) portion of the enterprises’ resources to countering—or hedging—that political risk . . . . Fannie Mae, in particular, makes no secret of its attempts to influence federal policy toward the GSEs as a means of controlling political risk . . . . Significantly, too, Fannie Mae explicitly includes the contribution to preserving its ‘franchise’ when evaluating the performance of executive staff. CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, ASSESSING THE PUBLIC COSTS AND BENEFITS OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 36–37 (1996) (internal citations omitted). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 228 enforced.37 It has long been recognized that GSEs are a special type of federal instrumentality.38 Other federal instrumentalities include most commercial banks and thrift institutions and other for-profit and nonprofit institutions chartered to serve public purposes.39 In contrast to those other instrumentalities, the officers and directors of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac seem to have had a much more difficult time balancing their fiduciary responsibilities to shareholders against the public purposes of their charter acts.40 Pressure from stakeholders to carry out public purposes,41 too, has conflicted with the GSEs’ responsibility to maintain themselves as sources of long-term 37 Richard Syron, Freddie Mac’s former CEO, pointed to this issue: Freddie Mac is a shareholder-owned corporation, chartered for the public purpose of supporting America’s mortgage finance markets, and operating under government mandates. We had obligations to Congress and to the public to promote our chartered purposes of increasing affordability, liquidity and stability in housing finance, which included some very specific low-income housing goals. Syron Statement, supra note 34. 38 STANTON, MERCANTILIST COMPANIES, supra note 5, at 13–32 ch.2. 39 See, e.g., THOMAS H. STANTON, A STATE OF RISK: WILL GOVERNMENT-SPONSORED ENTERPRISES BE THE NEXT FINANCIAL CRISIS? App. A, at 205–07 (1991) [hereinafter STANTON, A STATE OF RISK]; Thomas H. Stanton, Federal Supervision of Safety and Soundness of GovernmentSponsored Enterprises, 5 ADMIN. L.J. 395 (1991) [hereinafter Stanton, Federal Supervision]. 40 Richard Syron, Freddie Mac’s former CEO, faced this problem: Freddie Mac chief executive Richard F. Syron . . . said yesterday that conflicting demands on the government-chartered mortgage giant have made his job “almost impossible.” On the eve of Freddie Mac’s quarterly earnings report, Syron said that the McLean company has been whipsawed by the dual tasks of creating profit for private investors and serving the public by boosting the housing market. “What this organization is all about is balancing among the different missions,” Syron said in an interview. “It makes the job almost impossible.” Jeffrey H. Birnbaum & David S. Hilzenrath, Freddie CEO Feels Strain of Firm’s Twin Missions, WASH. POST, Aug. 6, 2008, at D01. 41 See, e.g., Syron Statement, supra note 34. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 229 strength to the housing market.42 Perhaps most eloquent on this issue was Daniel Mudd, the former CEO of Fannie Mae, who testified in December 2008: I would advocate moving the GSEs out of No Man’s Land. Events have shown how difficult it is to balance financial, capital, market, housing, shareholder, bondholder, homeowner, private, and public interests in a crisis of these proportions. We should examine whether the economy and the markets are better served by fully private or fully public GSEs.43 There were several reasons why Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were susceptible to being whipsawed between their fiduciary obligations to shareholders and their public purposes. One source of mischief was the fact that the two companies were chartered by an act of Congress rather than by an independent federal administrative agency. Members of Congress could constantly pressure Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac to undertake unwise lending policies. The two GSEs complied as a way to buy loyalty from the relevant congressional committees that otherwise might accede to requests from the Treasury or others to impose higher capital requirements or other restrictions that were unwelcome to shareholders. For example, Mr. Mudd testified that he felt pressure to increase Fannie Mae’s market activity even as other 42 [W]e have to confront the future of the secondary mortgage market, which will, I believe, shape the other decisions. That has to be the first principle as we . . . evaluate the options for Fannie Mae’s and Freddie Mac’s future. A second principle is that the Enterprises or any successors should have a well-defined and internally consistent mission based on their fundamental role in the mortgage market. Their mission activities should not require excessive risk taking as it did in the past. Lockhart, supra note 19. 43 The Role of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in the Financial Crisis: Hearing Before H. Comm. on Oversight and Government Reform, 110th Cong. 25–26 (2008) (written statement of Daniel H. Mudd, Former Interim CEO of Fannie Mae), available at http://oversight.house.gov/story. asp?ID=2252. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 230 institutions were stepping back because of declining market conditions.44 Stakeholder pressure to serve public purposes was substantial; by contrast, far fewer stakeholders pushed to ensure effective supervision of safety and soundness.45 In addition, the GSEs selected a political strategy of achieving short-term goals at the potential cost of longer term achievements. Their refusal to accept bank-type capital requirements and a bank-type supervisory framework for accountability has already been mentioned.46 The GSEs marshaled so much political power that they simply dominated their environment and dampened feedback signals that might have helped company officials to make better decisions.47 In return, however, the GSEs had to buy off stakeholders with large volumes of mortgage purchases that they, or at least their risk officers, knew were unwise.48 In their governance shortcomings, the two GSEs compounded the more general problem that the current debacle has revealed. Former Federal Reserve Chairman, Alan Greenspan, put it best: I made a mistake in presuming that the self interest of organizations, specifically banks and others, was such 44 Id. JONATHAN G.S. KOPPELL, THE POLITICS OF QUASI-GOVERNMENT: HYBRID ORGANIZATIONS AND THE DYNAMICS OF BUREAUCRATIC CONTROL 107, Cambridge University Press (2003). 46 See sources cited supra notes 9–17. 47 This problem is analyzed with respect to the two GSEs’ failed internal controls in Stanton, Lessons for Design and Accountability, supra note 27. 48 See sources cited supra note 20. Confidential company documents released by the House Committee on Oversight and Government Reform on December 9, 2008 detail some of the pressures on the companies and the mistakes made by the GSEs during 2005 through 2007. In particular, these documents indicate that the GSEs sought yield and market share despite added risk from nontraditional mortgage products and warnings from risk officers. Fannie Mae Office of Corporate Strategy, Memorandum to Daniel Mudd . . . from Gary Friend, Subject: CONFIDENTIAL Cambridge Summary, July 7, 2006, available at http://oversight.house.gov/documents/ 20081209131806.pdf (“Single Family’s strategy is to say ‘yes’ to our customers by increasing purchases of sub-prime and Alt-A loans . . . .”). 45 STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 231 that they were best capable of protecting their own shareholders and the equity in the firms.49 There are significant governance implications of this admission, coming as it does from a firm believer in the efficiency of market forces.50 Not only GSEs, but other financial firms also sought ways to increase their leverage and reduce the quality of their government supervision.51 There was a difference, though. As they served the perceived interests of their shareholders, banks and other investors were filled with the irrational exuberance of the market bubble. In addition, the GSEs faced (and failed to manage) stakeholder pressure to engage in activities that they probably knew (as their risk officers did), could inflict serious harm on the companies.52 B. GSEs Gain Virtually Unstoppable Political Power The GSE combines private ownership with government backing in a way that creates a political force that can dominate virtually any safety-and-soundness framework. The statutory framework of GSEs also creates special financial vulnerability because of incentives that GSEs have to appoint CEOs and senior management that are politically adept and who may not necessarily be experienced at managing a major financial 49 Kevin G. Hall, Greenspan Takes Some Blame for Financial Meltdown, MCCLATCHY NEWSPAPERS, Oct. 23, 2008, available at http://www. mcclatchydc.com/staff/kevin_hall/v-print/story/54712.html. 50 Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Fed. Res. Bd., Speech to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago’s Forty-first Annual Conference on Bank Structure: Risk Transfer and Financial Stability (May 5, 2005) (“Except where market discipline is undermined by moral hazard, for example, because of federal guarantees of private debt, private regulation generally has proved far better at constraining excessive risk-taking than has government regulation.”). 51 See, e.g., Stephen Labaton, The Reckoning: Agency’s ‘04 Rule Let Banks Pile Up New Debt, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 3, 2008 (reporting an SEC rule change which allowed investment banks to increase leverage significantly, enacted at behest of the regulated firms). 52 See sources cited supra note 20. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 232 institution.53 A GSE lives or dies according to the terms of its enabling legislation.54 Especially GSEs such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac that are directly chartered by Congress have tended (albeit not invariably) to select CEOs because of their ability to manage political risk rather than the risks that derive from their financial activities.55 This was seen in the newest GSE, Farmer Mac, which returned to Congress several times since its original authorization in 1987 requesting adjustments to its charter powers so that it could offer increasingly profitable financial services. Farmer Mac has never been a strong success in public policy terms56 and has invested heavily in assets that have 57 nothing to do with meeting public needs. 53 KOPPELL, supra note 45, at 101 (“ . . . Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac rosters boast numerous alumni of the executive and legislative branches . . . Furthermore, there is an impressive history of GSE executives crossing back into government service, giving the company advantages in terms of access, and sympathy, at the highest levels.”). 54 STANTON, MERCANTILIST COMPANIES, supra note 5, at 70–75 (“From mercantilist times, companies with special charter privileges have understood that their ultimate success or failure hinges even more on politics than on the efficient provision of services.”). 55 KOPPELL, supra note 45, at 99 (“[S]ince every aspect of their operations can be affected by congressional action, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have powerful incentives to devote significant attention to Congress and politics in general. Thus one can conclude that GSEs will possess resources and motive to expend these resources for political advantage.”) (emphasis in original). 56 U.S. GEN. ACCT. OFFICE, REP. TO THE CHAIRMAN, SUBCOMMITTEE ON CAPITAL MARKETS, SEC. AND GOV’T-SPONSORED ENTERPRISES, COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND FIN. SERVICES, HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES, FARMER MAC: REVISED CHARTER ENHANCES SECONDARY MARKET ACTIVITY, BUT GROWTH DEPENDS ON VARIOUS FACTORS, GAO/GGD-99-85 (May 1999). 57 Among other investments having nothing to do with its public purpose, in September 2008 Farmer Mac held in its investment portfolio $50.0 million of Fannie Mae floating rate preferred stock and $60.0 million of Lehman Brothers senior debt securities. After taking losses on these investments the GSE was recapitalized on September 30, 2008 by issuing new stock to institutions of the Farm Credit System, another GSE, and thereby averted STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 233 Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac made a practice of mastering political risk, both by providing blandishments to favored members of the political establishment and other stakeholders, and by aggressively containing threats to what the companies considered their franchise value.58 The GSEs are active participants in the process of influencing policymakers, especially those who are in positions to affect their charter legislation.59 On April 19, 2006, Freddie Mac paid a record fine to the Federal Election Commission to settle charges that the company violated federal law by using company resources to hold some $1.7 million in fundraisers, many involving the thenChairman of the House Financial Services Committee.60 That Committee is responsible for the legislation that created both Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and periodically considered legislation to address shortcomings in their supervision.61 insolvency. See Farmer Mac, Quarterly Report (Form 10-Q), at 44 (Nov. 10, 2008). 58 This has been a long-standing policy. In 1991 Representative Jim Leach (R-IA) stated: [I]t is not surprising that Fannie and Freddie are beginning to exhibit that arrogant characteristic of a duopoly, controlling 90% of the market. Such market dominance allows for heavy-handed approaches to competitors, to financial intermediaries, and to consumers. Competitors such as community based savings and loan associations and commercial banks are also users of GSE services. They are understandably apprehensive about expressing reservations about their practices in fear of retaliation. Likewise, would-be competitors such as securities firms run well known market risks if they object or attempt to compete with Fannie and Freddie. The two GSEs distribute billions of dollars of business on Wall Street and have a reputation of not cottoning to challengers of the status quo. H.COMM. ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS, H.R. Rep. No. 102206, at 122 (1991) (Dissenting Views of Representative Jim Leach from Report to accompany H.R. 2900 on the Government-Sponsored Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and Soundness Act of 1991). 59 KOPPELL, supra note 45, at 99. 60 See, e.g., Stanton, Lessons for Design and Accountability, supra note 27. 61 Id. Almost all of the legislation cited supra in note 9, falls within the jurisdiction of the House Financial Services Committee. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 234 Professor Jonathan Koppell notes that “the characteristics that distinguish government-sponsored enterprises from traditional government agencies and private companies endow Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac with unique political resources.”62 The potential inability of government to supervise safety and soundness of the GSEs has long been recognized. The Treasury pointed this out in a 1991 study of GSEs: The problem of avoiding capture appears to be particularly acute in the case of regulation of GSEs. The principal GSEs are few in number; they have highly qualified staffs; they have strong support for their programs from special interest groups; and they have significant resources with which to influence political outcomes. A weak financial regulator would find GSE political power overwhelming and even the most powerful and respected government agencies would find regulating such entities a challenge.63 The Treasury knew whereof it spoke. There are at least two cases on record where the Treasury Department, which had no safety-and-soundness regulatory authority over Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, reportedly came under pressure and agreed to make its reported views more congenial to the two companies.64 62 KOPPELL, supra note 45, at 97. TREASURY DEPARTMENT, 1991 REPORT OF THE SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY ON GOVERNMENT-SPONSORED ENTERPRISES 8 (1991). 64 On the weakening of a 1996 Treasury report on desirability and feasibility of removing government sponsorship from Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, see, for example, Jackie Calmes, Federal Mortgage Firm Is Facing New Assault to Privileged Status: But Fannie Has Clout to Counter the Agencies That Seek to Privatize It, WALL ST. J., May 14, 1986, at 1; Chairman Richard Baker, comments, U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Banking and Financial Services, Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Securities, and Government-Sponsored Enterprises, Oversight of the Federal National Mortgage Association [Fannie Mae] and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation [Freddie Mac], 104th Congress, 2nd session 136–41 (July 24, 1996). For discussion of possible pressure in 1991 on Treasury to state that HUD would be an appropriate regulator of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, see Thomas H. Stanton, Increasing the Accountability of Government-Sponsored Enterprises: Next Steps, 51 PUB. ADMIN. REV. 572 63 STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 235 Thanks to the lobbying power of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, OFHEO was, at its creation, an institution that lacked the capacity to do its job.65 OFHEO was limited by the appropriations process and had a budget that was much smaller, in comparison to its responsibilities, than the budgets of federal bank regulators.66 Whenever OFHEO tried to do its job well, as in the 2004 Special Examination Report on Fannie Mae, it experienced political pressure.67 Fannie Mae lobbyists generated a congressional request for the Inspector General (IG) of the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) to investigate OFHEO’s conduct of the special examination.68 Between October 2002 and June 2004, there were three other congressional requests for IG investigations of OFHEO.69 Fannie Mae lobbyists also tried to use the appropriations process to force a change in the leadership of OFHEO. They convinced the relevant Senate Appropriations Subcommittee to try to withhold $10 million from OFHEO’s appropriation until a new OFHEO director was appointed.70 The enactment of a stronger supervisory framework in 2008 meant that the new regulator, the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA), was no longer subject to the appropriations process.71 However, the political strength of the GSEs was reflected in the fact that the new legislation, improving as it did (1991), and articles cited therein. 65 STANTON, MERCANTILIST COMPANIES, supra note 5, at 42. 66 See, e.g., Stanton, Lessons for Design and Accountability, supra note 27. 67 OFFICE OF FEDERAL HOUSING ENTERPRISE OVERSIGHT, REPORT OF THE SPECIAL EXAMINATION OF FANNIE MAE 273–77 (May 2006), available at http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/747/FNMSPECIALEXAM.pdf. 68 Id. at 273. 69 Id. 70 Id. at 284. 71 Section 1106 of the Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008 (HERA), Pub. L. 110-289, amended the 1992 Federal Housing Enterprises Safety and Soundness Act to remove the new regulator from the appropriations process. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 236 on the old law, continued to deny the regulator the mandate, discretion, or authority to regulate safety and soundness that federal bank regulators have long possessed.72 The new Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008 (“HERA”) became law less than two months before Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac failed.73 Ultimately the two GSEs were not well-served by their tradition of selecting politically capable CEOs who could fend off the kind of supervision that a more capable regulator might have been able to provide.74 Because of their government backing and low capital requirements in their charters, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac gained immense market power.75 They doubled in size every five 76 years or so until their failure in 2008, when the two companies had funded over $5 trillion of mortgages—over 40 percent of the mortgage market.77 Their market power gave them political power. Whenever someone would urge regulatory reform, such as higher capital standards to reduce the GSEs’ dangerous leverage, huge numbers of constituents could be expected to flood Capitol Hill.78 In turn, that political power further entrenched the GSEs’ 72 To give but one example, the new law required the new regulator to conduct an estimated 25–30 rulemakings, often with short deadlines, to implement key provisions of the act. The bank regulators have discretion in many of the areas where HERA sought to impose inflexibility upon the FHFA through required rulemakings. 73 President Bush signed HERA into law on July 30, 2008; Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac went into conservatorship on September 7, 2008. 74 See, e.g., Stanton, Lessons for Design and Accountability, supra note 27, at 844 (“What does effective accountability mean? First, feedback is essential for effective operations . . . . Many examples exist, in both the private and public sectors, of how too much autonomy can lead to subsequent failure.”). 75 STANTON, MERCANTILIST COMPANIES, supra note 5, at 70–75. 76 See, e.g., figures presented in STANTON, supra note 5, at 4. 77 See, e.g., Nelson D. Schwartz, A History of Public Aid During Crises, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 7, 2008, at A27. 78 Observers have long noted this pattern. David A. Vise, The Money Machine: How Fannie Mae Wields Power, WASH. POST, Jan. 16, 1995, at A14 (“Builders, real estate brokers and bankers across the country rely so STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 237 market power. The failure of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac shows the shortcomings of the GSE as an organizational model. However sound the accountability structure may be when the organization begins, the incentive to satisfy private owners will lead a GSE to try to weaken safety and soundness oversight and reduce capital standards. Both Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac arguably had more effective accountability structures when they were chartered as GSEs than when they were supervised by OFHEO. Between 1968 and 1992, when OFHEO was established, both companies had successfully removed government controls that they considered unacceptable.79 In short, the drive to satisfy shareholders is intense and can easily overwhelm considerations for the financial system, the housing system, and American taxpayers. III. EVALUATING THE GSE AS AN ORGANIZATIONAL FORM A. Four Criteria Help to Evaluate Organizations That Carry Out Public Purposes: Capacity, Flexibility, Accountability, and Life-Cycle Four criteria are helpful in evaluating the quality of government agencies and instrumentalities that carry out public purposes:80 heavily on Fannie Mae for mortgage funds that they live in fear of offending the firm and routinely defend it in Washington.”). 79 For example, when Freddie Mac was chartered as a GSE in 1970 its board of directors consisted of three federal officials rather than a shareholder-controlled board; when Fannie Mae was chartered in 1968 its charter contained provisions permitting the HUD Secretary to fix the capitalization of the GSE at 6.6 percent, significantly higher than the 2.5 percent permitted by the 1992 Act. 80 See, e.g., Thomas H. Stanton, Moving Toward More Capable Government: A Guide to Organizational Design, in MEETING THE CHALLENGE OF 9/11: BLUEPRINTS FOR MORE EFFECTIVE GOVERNMENT 25 (2006) [hereinafter Stanton, Moving Toward More Capable Government]; Thomas H. Stanton, The Administration of Medicare, 60 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 1373 (2003) [hereinafter Stanton, Administration of Medicare]. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 238 Capacity: What is the capacity of the organization, in terms of people, administrative budget, systems, and organization, to carry out its public purposes? Flexibility: What flexibility does the organization have, under the law and in practice, to carry out its public purposes? Accountability: How well is the organization held accountable for (1) carrying out its public purposes, and (2) its stewardship of public resources? Life Cycle: As the organization matures, what strengths and shortcomings manifest themselves? For different organizations, different measures will become more critical than others in understanding strengths and weaknesses. As a general rule, to the extent that weaknesses appear, government agencies may have difficulty with the measures of capacity and flexibility, while privately owned instrumentalities may have difficulty with accountability.81 Numerous organizations of all types have difficulty with lifecycle, and the ability to remain active, focused, and useful over many years.82 Government-sponsored enterprises are privately owned institutions free from the budgetary and other constraints imposed on government agencies.83 As such, they tend to develop significant capacity and flexibility compared to government agencies that serve the same economic sector.84 A comparison of mortgage operations of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, on the one hand, and the Federal Housing Administration 81 Stanton, Moving Toward More Capable Government, supra note 80, at 25; Stanton, Administration of Medicare, supra note 80. 82 Stanton, Moving Toward More Capable Government, supra note 80, at 25; Stanton, Administration of Medicare, supra note 80. 83 Thomas H. Stanton & Ronald C. Moe, Government Corporations and Government Sponsored Enterprises, in TOOLS OF GOVERNMENT: A GUIDE TO THE NEW GOVERNANCE 85 (Lester M. Salamon ed., 2002) [hereinafter Stanton & Moe] (“Indeed, GSEs can, and usually do, become virtually autonomous from the government that charters them.”). 84 Stanton, Reducing Government Involvement, supra note 7. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 239 (FHA), on the other, displays this pattern. While Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were able to dedicate substantial resources to building their automated underwriting and other mortgagerelated systems, the federal budget process has constrained FHA from making similar needed investments even though they are essential to the future success of the agency.85 On the other hand, the issue of accountability is salient for GSEs, and for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in particular. As private companies operating with substantial government subsidies, GSEs often grow to dominate their markets.86 Market power leads to political power,87 which in turn leads to favorable changes to the GSE’s charter that help expand its market power and reduce the effectiveness of any accountability framework government may seek to apply to the GSEs. Finally, the issue of life cycle is also important for the GSEs. The rapid growth of GSEs combined with their ability to dominate their government regulator and other accountability measures and avoid being required to adopt prudent capital standards can lead to flawed business decisions.88 The current crisis in the mortgage market highlights problems of GSE accountability and life cycle with special force. B. GSE Vulnerabilities Will Not Disappear Merely by Changing Regulation or Governance Proposals to craft special rules such as regulating the GSEs as public utilities89 or limiting them to cooperative ownership90 85 Steve Preston, Secretary, HUD, Prepared Remarks at the National Press Club (Nov. 19, 2008), available at http://www.hud.gov/news/speeches/ 2008-11-19.cfm. 86 STANTON, MERCANTILIST COMPANIES, supra note 5, at 3 (“Thanks to their special government benefits, GSEs have grown rapidly to dominate many market segments, especially in housing (Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Banks) and student loans (Sallie Mae).”). 87 See supra note 78. 88 See, e.g., Stanton, Lessons for Design and Accountability, supra note 27. 89 See, e.g., Steven Sloan & Emily Flitter, Paulson’s Third Way: GSEs STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 240 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY will not overcome the vulnerabilities of the GSE as an institutional form that is based on political dominance. Such proposals to create a different accountability framework or governance structure for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac do not change the assessment of the GSE’s organizational form. Most importantly, the issue of political dominance of the GSEs over their regulators, and GSE influence over their congressional authorizing committees, would not go away even if these changes were actually implemented. Some have suggested that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac can be regulated as public utilities. This suggestion has several defects. First, utility regulation is designed to address the problem that public utilities benefit from scale economies that may give them characteristics of monopolies;91 price regulation by a public utility commission seeks to prevent a public utility from imposing monopoly pricing on its customers.92 In other words, rather than limiting the size of a public utility, government accepts a utility’s dominant market position and seeks to limit the high prices that could result. But taxpayers are at risk if the GSEs grow to hold a dominant position in the mortgage market.93 The need to control monopoly pricing is not Taking Utility Role, AM. BANKER, Jan. 8, 2009. The public utility model is described in R. S. Seiler, Jr., Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac as InvestorOwned Utilities, 11 J. PUB. BUDGETING, ACCT. & FIN. MGMT. 117 (1999). 90 At the time of this writing, such proposals are circulating informally among federal agencies and stakeholder groups. 91 Seiler, supra note 89, at 121, 124 (“[T]he utility industries have generally exhibited economies of scale . . . . The superior technology and monopoly franchise of a traditional utility gives the firm considerable market power.”). 92 Id. at 124 (“[W]hen only one firm is allowed to serve a market, the company has an incentive to set prices above marginal cost, restrict output, and engage in price discrimination, in order to earn monopoly profits. To limit these incentives, governments traditionally imposed limits on the rates of return that utilities could earn and required that their rate structures be fair and equitable.”). 93 Stanton, supra note 27, at 840 (“As the GSEs have grown Treasury Secretary John Snow, Comptroller General David M. Walker, Congressional Budget Office Director Douglas Holtz-Eakin, and Federal Reserve Chairmen STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 241 as much a concern for today’s taxpayers as is the need to limit the size of GSEs and their accompanying financial risks. The public utility model, with its focus on price regulation, is not relevant to that problem. Indeed, a regulator with authority to supervise pricing could potentially decide to permit a GSE to charge high prices as a way to build a strong capital cushion.94 Secondly, regulated companies too often capture their regulators.95 As political scientist Marver Bernstein noted, regulatory commissions are frequently dominated by the interests that they are supposed to regulate.96 Thus, under any new regulatory scheme, the GSEs would simply shift the application of their political power from domination of their past regulators to the new public utility regulator. Third, the creation of a separate utility-type regulator for the GSEs would not combine GSE supervision with the responsibilities of a regulator that supervises banks and thrifts as Alan Greenspan and Ben Bernanke have warned about the possibility of financial failure at a GSE spreading to the many holders of GSE obligations such as commercial banks and foreign central banks. This is what is known as systemic risk, which is the possibility that a failure at one institution causes market turmoil that spreads to other institutions in the financial system, with potentially serious effects for the performance of the U.S. economy.”). 94 This is similar to the position of Gary Gorton, Slapped in the Face by the Invisible Hand: Banking and the Panic of 2007 5 (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Conference Paper, 2009), available at http://www.frbatlanta.org/ news/CONFEREN/09fmc/gorton.pdf (creating a stable banking structure “will require that a valuable charter be recreated for firms that are deemed ‘banks’”). 95 See, e.g., Willem H. Buiter, Lessons from the North Atlantic Financial Crisis 36–38 (May 28, 2008), available at http://www.newyorkfed. org/research/conference/2008/rmm/buiter.pdf (paper prepared for presentation at the conference “The Role of Money Markets” jointly organized by Columbia Business School and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York on May 29–30, 2008). 96 MARVER BERNSTEIN, REGULATING BUSINESS BY INDEPENDENT COMMISSION 92 (1955) (“During old age the working agreement that a commission reaches with the regulated interests becomes so fixed that the regulatory agency has no creative force left to mobilize against the regulated groups.”). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 242 well as GSEs. Rather, it would encourage the preferential capital and supervisory requirements that lie at the core of GSE financial vulnerability.97 In short, application of a public utility model to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac would perpetuate many of the vulnerabilities and large-scale risks of the GSE model that lie at the root of their failure in 2008. Another idea being discussed informally, though not yet published in a formal treatment, is to change the governance structure of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac so that they would be owned and controlled by companies that do business with them—a cooperative structure. The cooperative governance structure also fails to add quality to the GSE model. This was seen among the GSEs in the financial failure of the Farm Credit System in the mid-1980s and the troubled financial condition of the Federal Home Loan Banks today.98 While the investor-owned GSE seeks to increase risk to serve its investor owners, the cooperative GSE has an incentive to serve the cooperative owners who use its services.99 That incentive led the Farm 97 See, e.g., Thomas H. Stanton, Government Sponsored Enterprises (GSEs): Why is Effective Government Supervision Hard to Achieve?, Address to the 37th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago (May 10, 2001) (“ . . . (1) the government subsidy allows GSEs to expand and increase their risk-taking without facing the market discipline that constrains other companies; (2) the GSEs have both incentive and ability to influence or dominate the political process; and (3) the unusual legal structure of GSEs involves complexities that policymakers may not fully understand. This paper contends that all of these factors make government supervision difficult, if not impossible.”). 98 Steven Sloan, Insurance Fund for FHLBs is on the Table: Idea Could Help Instill Confidence, Provide Backstop, AM. BANKER, June 3, 2009, at 1 (“As the Federal Home Loan banks continue to struggle with charges on their mortgage holdings, the Federal Housing Finance Agency is considering the creation of an insurance fund that could absorb losses at a troubled Home Loan bank.”). 99 See, e.g., Stanton, Moving Toward More Capable Government, supra note 80, at 75 (“For the cooperative, governance by a board of directors means attention to the needs of the owners that use the cooperative’s services. Thus, a cooperative such as the Farm Credit System in the past showed a tendency to underprice its services . . . .”). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 243 Credit System to provide credit to its cooperative borrowers below the GSE’s own cost of funds.100 Such an approach was not sustainable and led to the system declaring insolvency in the mid-1980s. The experience of the cooperative GSEs shows that turning Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into cooperatives would not reduce their incentives or capacity to dominate the GSE regulator and avoid prudential requirements such as bank-type capital standards. IV. WHAT TO DO WITH THE GSES NOW THAT THEY ARE IN GOVERNMENT HANDS As instruments of government policy,101 the future of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac should depend on the amount and kind of support that the markets actually need. More substantial government support is needed in the next few years, as the effects of the collapsing housing credit bubble make themselves felt in a weakened mortgage market, rather than in five years or so, when the housing markets have returned to greater strength and stability. A. The Government Should Place Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into Receivership The government placed Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into conservatorship rather than receivership. Unlike receivership, the voluntary acceptance of conservatorship by Fannie Mae or 102 Freddie Mac was not subject to litigation, which could have 100 Stanton, Lessons for Design and Accountability, supra note 27, at 421–23. 101 Political scientist Lester Salamon considers the GSEs to be what he calls “tools of government.” A GSE, although not a government agency or other part of the formal government, is a tool of government that helps to carry out public purposes. See Stanton & Moe, supra note 83. 102 Section 1369(b)(4) (“Appointment of Conservators”) of the 1992 Act provides that “[a]ppointment of a conservator pursuant to consent of the enterprise under subsection (a)(2) shall not be subject to judicial review under this subsection.” Codified at 12 U.S.C. § 4619(b)(2)(2008). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 244 further troubled the financial markets at a difficult time. Placing a failed financial institution directly into conservatorship violates the customary practice of the federal bank and thrift regulators who first place an institution into receivership, then separate the assets into a “good-bank/badbank” structure and send the good bank, cleaned out of troubled assets, into conservatorship or bridge-bank status.103 Placing an institution into receivership removes the shareholders of the defunct institution. Thus, when IndyMac, a large thrift institution with over $32 billion in assets, failed,104 it was placed into receivership.105 The receiver then transferred the deposits and most of the assets to a newly chartered thrift, IndyMac Federal Bank,106 with the FDIC as conservator.107 It is now time to place Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into receivership. As past losses materialize and are recognized by the two GSEs, it is clear that both institutions have lost much more than their entire net worth.108 Placing both companies into 103 Appointment of a receiver for an insolvent bank or thrift institution with federally insured deposits is required under conditions specified in 12 U.S.C. § 1831o(h)(3)(C) (2008). Authority to establish a bridge bank is found in 12 U.S.C. § 1821(m)(2008). 104 Press Release, Fed. Deposit Ins. Corp., FDIC Establishes IndyMac Fed. Bank, FSB as Successor to IndyMac Bank, F.S.B., Pasadena, Cal. (July 11, 2008), available at http://www.fdic.gov/news/news/press/2008/pr08056. html. 105 See, e.g., Chief Financial Officer’s (CFO) Report to the Board, Executive Summary Third Quarter 2008, Fed. Deposit Ins. Corp., available at http://www.fdic.gov/about/strategic/corporate/cfo_report_3rdqtr_08/exec_ summary.html (“During the third quarter of 2008, the FDIC was named receiver for . . . IndyMac Bank of Pasadena, California.”). 106 Sheila C. Bair, Chairman, Fed. Deposit Ins. Corp., A Review of Foreclosure Mitigation Efforts Before the Fin. Servs. Comm. U.S. House of Representatives (Sep. 17, 2008), available at http://www.fdic.gov/news/ news/speeches/archives/2008/chairman/spsep1708.html (“As the Committee knows, the former IndyMac Bank, F.S.B., Pasadena, California, was closed July 11. The FDIC is conservator for a new institution, IndyMac Federal Bank, F.S.B. (IndyMac Federal), to which the accounts and assets of the former IndyMac Bank, F.S.B. were transferred.”). 107 Id. 108 Fannie Mae Seeks $10.7B in US Aid After 2Q Loss, N.Y. TIMES, STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 245 receivership will help to remove an inherent conflict in the government’s position. Technically, conservatorship means that the government is working to restore the companies to financial health;109 the government has preserved the shareholders in the two companies and allowed their stock to trade freely. This is inconsistent with key aspects of the government’s need to use the two companies to support the mortgage market, now that the value of the holdings of private shareholders in the companies is zero.110 Until shareholders are removed from the equation, officers and directors of the two companies will be conflicted as to their fiduciary responsibilities. Do they price mortgage purchases low to support the market or do they price higher to 111 The two replenish the companies’ shareholder value? companies and their managers appear to be caught in the strong contradiction between their obligations to serve their remaining shareholders and the needs of the housing market.112 If the government placed both companies into receivership, Aug. 7, 2009, http://dealbook.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/08/07/fannie-maeseeks-107-billion-in-aid-after-loss/?scp=1&sq=fannie&st=cse (“Fannie Mae’s new request for $10.7 billion from the Treasury Department will bring the total for Fannie and Freddie to nearly $96 billion.”). 109 “The FHFA, as Conservator, may take all actions necessary and appropriate to (1) put the Company in a sound and solvent condition and (2) carry on the Company’s business and preserve and conserve the assets and property of the Company.” FEDERAL HOUSING FINANCE AGENCY, FACT SHEET: QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS ON CONSERVATORSHIP 2 (2008), http://www.fhfa.gov/webfiles/35/FHFACONSERVQA.pdf. 110 Kopecki, supra note 3. 111 The two companies themselves complain of the conflict in their roles in conservatorship. See Fannie Mae, Quarterly Report (Form 10-Q), at 7 (Sept. 30, 2008); Freddie Mac, Quarterly Report (Form 10-Q), at 5 (Sept. 30, 2008). 112 Zachary A. Goldfarb, Government-Picked Leader Resigns as Losses Pile Up, WASH. POST, Mar. 3, 2009, at D01 (“The government-appointed chief executive of Freddie Mac announced yesterday that he is stepping down . . . . David M. Moffett’s resignation comes amid growing losses at the McLean mortgage-finance company and unresolved questions about whether it should follow the path of a private firm trying to make its way back to profitability or that of a government agency whose overriding goal is carrying out public policy.”). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 246 then it could use Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac as agents of reform for the mortgage market.113 B. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Should Not Again Become GSEs To best support the mortgage market, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac should not again become privately owned organizations that operate with federal backing. For many reasons, it is important to now end the GSE status of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. First, the GSEs have now squandered a policy tool that government had used for decades: the perception of an implicit rather than explicit federal guarantee of their debt obligations.114 That means that government would need to provide some form of express guarantee if the GSEs were to be restored; providing an express government guarantee to only two companies, or even a few companies, would raise fundamental issues of fairness. Second, as was seen in the savings and loan debacle115 and now with the GSEs,116 the government has great difficulty managing the risks when it insures the liabilities of a specialized financial institution. If policymakers want to support the mortgage 113 For examples of government corporations successfully helping to address the consequences of earlier crises, see MARK K. CASSELL & SUSAN M. HOFFMAN, IBM CENTER FOR THE BUSINESS OF GOVERNMENT, MANAGING A $700 BILLION BAILOUT: LESSONS FROM THE HOME OWNERS’ LOAN CORPORATION (2009), http://www.businessofgovernment.org/pdfs/Cassell Report.pdf. 114 Stanton, Public Adminstration Theory, supra note 6, at 636 (“ . . . the Treasury’s infusion of capital starting on September 7, 2008, creates the perception of an explicit federal guarantee for the GSEs.”). 115 See, e.g., R. DAN BRUMBAUGH, JR., THRIFTS UNDER SIEGE at 179 (1988) (“Now, economic volatility and widespread information distribution are facts of life, and exogenous and endogenous economic volatility for thrifts and banks are rendering deposit insurance, with its implicit taxpayer burden, and balance-sheet regulation increasingly untenable.”). 116 See, e.g., STANTON, A STATE OF RISK, supra note 39, at 8–12 (comparing the institutional characteristics of savings and loan associations (S&Ls) with GSEs). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 247 market, they should authorize government guarantees of mortgages, or at most, mortgage-backed securities. Third, the government should not provide special charters to a limited number of specialized institutions. As the GSEs have shown, it is virtually impossible to protect the regulator of a few private institutions from being dominated.117 This is especially true if the regulated institutions operate under a law such as HERA,118 which provides for different rules, especially for capital, but also for other aspects of safety and soundness, than those applicable to other institutions in the same lines of business.119 Fourth, proposals to craft special rules such as trying to regulate the GSEs as public utilities or by limiting them to cooperative ownership will not overcome the vulnerabilities of the GSE as an institutional form that is based on political dominance. Consider each of these issues in turn. 1. The End of the Implicit Government Guarantee of GSE Obligations In earlier years, government was careful to preserve the option that it would decline to bail out holders of GSE obligations and GSE-guaranteed mortgage-backed securities.120 117 See, e.g., U.S. GEN. ACCOUNTING OFFICE, GOVERNMENT-SPONSORED ENTERPRISES: A FRAMEWORK FOR LIMITING GOVERNMENT’S EXPOSURE TO RISKS, GAO/GGD-91-90, May 1991, at 45 (“We also believe a regulator that oversees a single regulated entity may have difficulty remaining at arm’s length from that entity.”). 118 Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-289, (2008). 119 For example, a federal financial regulator needs discretion to set and adjust capital standards according to events as they occur. Compare the rulemaking requirements of HERA, section 1111(d)(3), with the much more flexible authority of the federal bank regulators at 12 U.S.C. § 3907(a)(2)(2008) (“Each appropriate Federal banking agency shall have the authority to establish such minimum level of capital for a banking institution as the appropriate Federal banking agency, in its discretion, deems to be necessary or appropriate in light of the particular circumstances of the banking institution.”). 120 Thus, the Fannie Mae Charter Act contains a requirement that: STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 248 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY Government officials regularly used careful language indicating that the government’s involvement merely created the perception of an implicit guarantee rather than an actual guarantee.121 These niceties began to erode with the financial rescue of the failed Farm Credit System in the mid-1980s and the government’s rush to support obligations of the Financing Corporation (FICO) in 1996.122 With the government support of holders of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac debt obligations and mortgage-backedsecurities as part of the government’s rescue of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac on September 7, 2008, the perception of implicit government backing of GSEs has become an anachronism.123 One consequence of the destruction of the implicit guarantee is that in the future, government will be required to provide either an express guarantee, backed by the full-faith and credit of the United States, or none at all. Another consequence is that, unlike the former implicit federal guarantee, explicit government guarantees are included in the federal budget. Thus, the Office The corporation shall insert appropriate language in all of its obligations issued under this subsection clearly indicating that such obligations, together with the interest thereon, are not guaranteed by the United States and do not constitute a debt or obligation of the United States or any agency or instrumentality thereof other than the corporation. 12 U.S.C. § 1719(b) (2008). The corresponding Freddie Mac Charter provision is found at 12 U.S.C. § 1455(h)(2) (2008). 121 See, e.g., U.S. GEN. ACCOUNTING OFFICE, HOUSING ENTERPRISES: POTENTIAL IMPACTS OF SEVERING GOVERNMENT SPONSORSHIP, GGD-96-120, May 1996, at 25 (“The most important benefit that the enterprises receive from their government-sponsored status, however, is an implicit one stemming from investors’ perception that the federal government would not allow the enterprises to default on their obligations.”). 122 On the former, see, STANTON, A STATE OF RISK, supra note 39, at 124. On the latter see, e.g., Associated Press, House Panel Backs Rescue of S & L. Fund, N.Y. TIMES, July 26, 1996, http://www.nytimes.com/1996/ 07/26/business/house-panel-backs-rescue-of-s-l-fund.html?scp=55&sq=%22 financing+corporation%22&st=nyt&pagewanted=print. The Financing Corporation is authorized by 12 U.S.C. § 1441 (2008). 123 Stanton, Public Adminstration Theory, supra note 6, at 636 (“ . . . the Treasury’s infusion of capital starting on September 7, 2008, creates the perception of an explicit federal guarantee for the GSEs.”). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 249 of Management and Budget (OMB) (which administers budgeting for credit programs for the Executive Branch),124 is likely to score borrowing by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (or their successor organizations performing similar functions) as a part of credit reform, comparable to the budget treatment of financial guarantees issued by Ginnie Mae (a wholly owned government corporation located in the Department of Housing and Urban Development that guarantees mortgage-backed securities insured or guaranteed by FHA or other government agencies).125 The days of the GSE as a source of an off-budget government subsidy for housing finance are coming to an end. 2. The Risks of Insuring Liabilities of Specialized Financial Institutions As periodic failures of federal guarantee programs have shown,126 the government can, and sometimes does, lose the capacity to supervise use of its financial guarantee. Losses occur when a federal program incurs defaults on loans that an agency guarantees, or on direct loans that an agency provides.127 For 124 OFFICE OF MGMT. AND BUDGET, EXEC. OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT, CIRCULAR NO. A-129, POLICIES FOR FEDERAL CREDIT PROGRAMS AND NONTAX RECEIVABLES (2000). 125 Ginnie Mae, the Government National Mortgage Association, was chartered in 1968 as a wholly owned government corporation at the time that Fannie Mae was chartered as a GSE. Both organizations are successors to the original Federal National Mortgage Association that until 1968 was a wholly owned government corporation. 12 U.S.C. § 1717 (2008). 126 See generally, LEONARD DOWNIE, JR., MORTGAGE ON AMERICA 143 (Praeger Publishers 1974) (discussing the failure of HUD single-family and multifamily programs in the early 1970s). 127 Credit budgeting requires a calculation of the so-called credit subsidy, i.e., the budgetary outlays that will be required to fund new loans or loan guarantees that the government provides each fiscal year. Credit reform recognizes that a loan’s true cost is . . . the net value of its cash flows over the life of the loan. This value is the loan’s “subsidy cost”, [sic] which is the net present value of a loan’s expected cash inflows and outflows over the life of the loan. For example, if the estimated present value of a direct loan’s cash STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 250 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY example, the FHA’s single-family mortgage insurance program128 currently would seem to be especially at risk of incurring high rates of defaults on mortgages that the FHA insures.129 However, a guarantee of assets rather than liabilities has several advantages for the government and taxpayers. First, asset guarantees are subject to oversight through the federal budget and the application of credit budgeting.130 This allows the Office of Management and Budget to monitor the risks involved in extending the guarantee and to provide regular feedback to the agency and program through the annual process of reestimating the budgetary costs.131 Such supervision and discipline is lacking for federal outflows equals $100 and the present value of its inflows equals $90, its subsidy cost is $10 and its subsidy rate is 10 percent. If an agency proposed to make $2,000 of these loans, it would seek an appropriation of 10 percent of the desired face value, or $200. Budgeting for loan programs with this present value-based accounting system represented a significant departure for the otherwise cash-based Federal budget. THOMAS H. STANTON, Loans and Loan Guarantees, in TOOLS OF GOVERNMENT, supra note 83, at 384. 128 The FHA program is explained on the HUD website. HUD, Federal Housing Administration, http://www.hud.gov/offices/hsg/fhahistory.cfm (last visited Aug. 10, 2009) (“The Federal Housing Administration, generally known as ‘FHA’, [sic] provides mortgage insurance on loans made by FHAapproved lenders throughout the United States and its territories. FHA insures mortgages on single family and multifamily homes including manufactured homes and hospitals. It is the largest insurer of mortgages in the world, insuring over 34 million properties since its inception in 1934.”). 129 See, e.g., Preston, supra note 85; Barry Meier, As FHA’s Role Grows, So Does the Risk of Fraud, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 10, 2008. 130 See supra note 124 and accompanying text. 131 The Office of Management and Budget annually estimates the risk of each federal credit program and the amount of subsidy that would need to be provided to offset the risk of loans and loan guarantees originated during the year. For data on credit programs for the most recent Fiscal Year, see Federal Credit Supplement: Budget of the U.S. Government Fiscal Year 2010, available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/fy2010/assets/ cr_supp.pdf (last visited Nov. 1, 2009). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 251 programs that guarantee liabilities rather than financial assets.132 Thus, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (“FDIC”) has been able to guarantee hundreds of billions of dollars of debt in response to the financial crisis, including obligations of troubled institutions such as Citigroup and Bank of America, without being accountable through the federal budget.133 Similarly, guarantees of corporate pension plan liabilities by the Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation (“PBGC”) are not subject to budget constraints.134 Second, it is less difficult to monitor the risks inherent in a guarantee of assets than in a guarantee of liabilities. For a guarantee of assets, the government must monitor the quality of origination, servicing, and collections, and the credit quality of the assets themselves.135 By contrast, monitoring a guarantee of liabilities of a financial institution involves trying to assess the quality of the institution’s management, its capitalization, its accounting practices, and many other potential sources of risk besides the quality of its assets. Third, as was seen most clearly in the savings and loan 132 F. Stevens Redburn, How Should the Government Measure Spending? The Uses of Accrual Accounting, 53 PUB. ADMIN. REV. 228 (1993). 133 OFFICE OF MGMT. & BUDGET, EXEC. OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT, ANALYTICAL PERSPECTIVES: BUDGET OF THE UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT, FISCAL YEAR 2009 69 (2008). The “Credit and Insurance” chapter is instructive when one compares budget treatment of credit programs, including direct loans and federal guarantees of financial assets, with guarantees of liabilities such as the FDIC guarantee of obligations of insolvent financial institutions. 134 Estimated losses on guarantees by the PBGC were estimated at $47 billion. Again, the Analytical Perspectives “Credit and Insurance” chapter is instructive when one compares budget treatment of credit programs, including direct loans and federal guarantees of financial assets, with guarantees of liabilities by the PBGC. See id. The law states that liabilities of the PBGC are not backed by the United States. 29 U.S.C. § 1302(g)(2) (2008) (“The United States is not liable for any obligation or liability incurred by the corporation.”). As with the backing of GSE obligations that the GSEs disavow in their loan documentation, no one believes this. See supra note 120. 135 Stanton, Public Adminstration Theory, supra note 6. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 252 debacle, a federal guarantee of an institution’s liabilities creates adverse incentives. When the government guarantees obligations of a financial firm through deposit insurance, for example, insured depositors lose incentive to monitor the safety and soundness of the institution to which they are lending money when they make a deposit. Unless the government supervises them closely, owners of such a financial institution, can in turn, take much greater risks than if investors were more vigilant in their obligations. This can greatly compound the government’s risk exposure, compared to the actual volume of liabilities that government believes it is guaranteeing.136 By contrast, when government guarantees financial assets or even pools of financial assets, it can provide for risk sharing that, at least in principle, can reduce the government’s potential losses. For all of these reasons, if government can avoid guaranteeing the liabilities of a private institution, it should do so. In the case of providing support for the residential mortgage market, this conclusion is bolstered by the fact that federal mortgage insurance, or perhaps a federal guarantee of pools of mortgages, with appropriate risk-sharing with the loan originator, can provide needed support for the mortgage market without incurring the risks involved in trying to guarantee the liabilities of a GSE.137 It also seems prudent that the future structure of housing finance must take account of the difficulty that both public and private sector managers can have in trying to manage a large volume of assets and mortgage-backed securities. 136 For example, that was the case with the savings and loan debacle. See, e.g., BRUMBAUGH, supra note 115; STANTON, A STATE OF RISK, supra note 39, at 8–12. 137 See, e.g., Stanton, Public Adminstration Theory, supra note 6, at 636 (“The benefit of this option is that it cleanly removes shareholders and current management from the equation and allows the government to pump federally backed funds into the mortgage market on a prudent basis.”). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 253 3. Special Charters and the Problem of Regulatory Capture Regulatory capture is a major problem for federal regulators in many parts of the economy.138 The problem is especially acute for a regulator of only a few institutions. Such a regulator can be expected to assume a parochial point of view compared to a regulator with responsibility for supervising a plethora of institutions with varying interests and perspectives.139 The problem becomes especially acute for institutions such as GSEs that fall into a hybrid category between other organizational types.140 Take, for example, the issue of appropriate capital standards: should GSE capital standards be set according to bank-type standards or according to the standards that state regulators apply to private mortgage-backed securities conduits? Economist Willem Buiter argues that what he calls “cognitive regulatory capture” can bring financial 138 See BERNSTEIN, supra note 96, at 295 (“By insulating themselves from popular political forces, the commissions have subjected themselves to undue influence from the regulated groups and tend to become protective spokesmen for the industries which they regulate.”); see also Buiter, supra note 95, at 36–41 (showing the power of what he calls “cognitive regulatory capture”). 139 The GAO has made similar observations and earlier recommended that all of the GSEs be supervised by a single high-level regulator: Because of its important responsibility to supervise the safety and soundness of all the enterprises, the members of the independent regulator’s board need to have sufficient status, respect in government and business, and financial expertise. GAO proposes a three-member board composed of a full-time chairperson who acts as the chief executive officer of the regulatory staff, the Secretary of the Treasury, and the Chairman of the Federal Reserve System. CHARLES BOWSHER, GOVERNMENT SPONSORED ENTERPRISES: A FRAMEWORK FOR LIMITING GOVERNMENT’S EXPOSURE TO RISKS GAO/GGD91–90, May 1991, at 8. This recommendation failed to be adopted, in part because it could have placed congressional jurisdiction over the regulator into a broad-based committee such as the House Ways and Means Committee rather than in the hands of the GSE authorizing committees. 140 STANTON, supra note 5, at 1. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 254 regulators into the cognitive mindset of the institutions that they regulate.141 Cognitive capture is not a product of corruption, but rather a process by which the regulator or relevant congressional actors internalize “as if by osmosis, the objectives, interests, and perception of reality of the vested interests they are meant to regulate and supervise . . . .”142 The dynamic of Buiter’s cognitive regulatory capture means that over time, a regulator can grow to favor the institutions that it regulates. Thus, a regulator with responsibility for supervising only the housing GSEs under a statute with a unique statement of capital requirements compared to other financial institutions, can gain motivation to move towards lower capital standards.143 This opens the door to regulatory arbitrage and the likelihood that the GSEs once again would resume their excessive growth, based on their regulatory advantages rather than on whether it makes sense to concentrate so much risk in a few specialized financial institutions. The inability of the Congress to set bank-type capital standards for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac or to create for them a supervisory framework that was at least as strong as the supervisory framework for banks,144 stands as a warning of the political dynamics that are at play here. As specialized institutions,145 GSEs tend to be the province of parochial 141 Buiter, supra note 95, at 37. Id. 143 See supra note 71 and accompanying text. In contrast to HERA, which maintains a distinct statutory framework for the GSEs, there are now consolidated statutory requirements for the bank and thrift regulators. The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Act, as amended, in 12 U.S.C. § 1813(q) (2008) defines “Appropriate Federal Banking Agency” to include the Office of Thrift Supervision (the thrift regulator) as well as the bank regulators and, in 12 U.S.C § 1818 (2008), grants common supervisory authority and imposes common responsibility upon each “appropriate federal banking agency” to apply remedies to deal with troubled institutions that are under their supervision. 144 See Stanton, Public Adminstration Theory, supra note 6, at 634–35. 145 See, e.g., STANTON, MERCANTILIST COMPANIES, supra note 5, at 8 (“Like thrifts, government-sponsored enterprises are specialized lenders. In return for their statutory benefits they are limited by law to serving 142 STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 255 committees or subcommittees of the Congress that are attuned to the benefits of GSEs for the stakeholders whom they serve, and are relatively insensitive to the need to protect ordinary taxpayers from having to pay for an expensive rescue.146 The prospect of differential capital and other supervisory requirements that permit regulatory arbitrage means that GSEs again can evolve to become not only “too big to fail,” but also too big to succeed.147 The failure of internal controls at both GSEs was revealed at Freddie Mac in 2003 and at Fannie Mae in 2004,148 when they were much smaller than they were when they failed completely several years later. More recently, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have shown, at great cost to the residential mortgage market and larger financial system, that the GSEs and their politically oriented managers lack the ability to manage such large institutions. One should not ignore the fact that many other kinds of financial institutions, including banks, thrifts, and investment banks and their holding companies also failed in the recent debacle. The point here is that the GSE can be replaced by a wholly owned government corporation to provide comparable prescribed kinds of borrowers or dealing in specified kinds of loans.”). 146 Thus, when considering whether to create the first safety-andsoundness regulator for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (which became OFHEO in 1992), members of the House Banking Committee joked about whether the legislation was necessary. Asked one Representative, “I’m just not sure exactly what we’re doing . . . . I still want to know what basic problem we’re attempting to fix.” Answered another, “Palpitations in the Treasury Department, cause unknown.” Jill Zuckman, Bills To Increase GSE Oversight Move Ahead in House, Senate, CONG. Q., Aug. 3, 1991, at 21–39. 147 See, e.g., GARY H. STERN & RON J. FELDMAN, TOO BIG TO FAIL: THE HAZARDS OF BANK BAILOUTS 26 (Brookings Institution Press 2004) (defining institutions that are too big to fail as so large, complex, or intertwined with the rest of the financial system that policymakers support the institution’s uninsured creditors—despite having no legal obligation to do so— for fear that the institution’s failure could cause an unacceptable amount of damage to other institutions and the larger financial system. Economic costs accrue “when weak market discipline associated with too big to fail induces banks to make suboptimal decisions.”). 148 Stanton, supra note 27, at 840–42. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 256 support to the mortgage market without incurring the political and financial risks inherent in the GSE’s hybrid organizational form. C. The Government Should Turn Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into Wholly Owned Government Corporations The government should promptly end Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac as investor-owned companies with perceived federal backing and turn them into wholly owned government corporations.149 At some specified time—say five years from now, when the mortgage market stabilizes once again— policymakers can decide the extent to which government support for the secondary mortgage market would be useful or affordable. The wholly owned government corporation is a special type of government agency that is intended to operate in a businesslike way.150 Government corporations are supposed to be financially self-sustaining, or at least potentially self-sustaining. They keep their books similar to a private firm and submit business-type budgets rather than government budgets each year. The idea of a government corporation is that it should seek to fund itself from its operations. If Congress decides to add noneconomic programs to a government corporation charter, then it should appropriate money to enable the government corporation to carry out these activities. In the current environment, when many people express concerns about the large size of government, it is helpful to remember that GSEs combine the involvement of government with the incentives of private owners to create a much larger, and economically more distorting, presence in the mortgage 149 Government Corporation Control Act, 31 U.S.C.A. § 9101 (2008) (defining the contours of the term “wholly owned government corporation”). 150 See, e.g., Stanton & Moe, supra note 83, at 81; Office of Management and Budget, Memorandum on Government Corporations, M-9605, at 3 (Dec. 8, 1995); U.S. Government Accountability Office, Government Corporations: Profiles of Existing Government Corporations, GGD-96-14, at 5 (1995). STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 257 market than occurs if a government corporation were quietly serving its mission without the drive to constant expansion that systematically occurs with any GSE.151 Transformed into government corporations, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac could carry out significant activities during the next five years. They could: 1. Lower the cost of mortgages to help consumers refinance out of adjustable rate and other kinds of mortgages that are proving difficult for many homeowners to repay. 2. Serve as vehicles to deliver improved federal support for homeowners who are forced into foreclosure by losing their jobs. 3. Provide essential consumer protections for borrowers, such as Alex Pollock’s one-page mortgage disclosure form.152 4. Devise and impose requirements that primary lenders and other participants in the mortgage process have appropriate financial strength and capability, accountability, and that they engage in appropriate risksharing before they are allowed to do business with the two companies. Implementation of some of these requirements may need to be deferred until the housing and mortgage markets regain some semblance of stability. 5. Adapt their Automated Underwriting Systems, and perhaps other systems and capabilities, for use by other federal agencies, starting with the FHA, and perhaps Ginnie Mae and the direct loan program for homeowners (part of the disaster loan program) of the Small Business 151 See, e.g., Stanton & Moe, supra note 83, at 82; see also STANTON, MERCANTILIST COMPANIES, supra note 5, at 4–6, (showing statistics of how all of the GSEs, whether investor-owned or cooperatives, virtually doubled in size every five years). 152 ALEX POLLOCK, THE BASIC FACTS ABOUT YOUR MORTGAGE LOAN (American Enterprise Institute 2007), available at http://www.aei.org/docLib/ 20070913_20070515_PollockPrototype.pdf. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 258 Administration.153 In short, the government could turn the collapse of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into an opportunity to fashion important rules of conduct for those types of participants in the housing market that have served American consumers and taxpayers so poorly. The government also could use the GSEs to help shore up the FHA by providing technical and IT systems support. Once they become wholly owned government corporations without the need to serve a mix of public and private objectives, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac could play major roles in supporting the housing market. Congress would be well advised to place a sunset provision of perhaps five years into each government corporation charter. A sunset date, which formally would terminate the corporation charter and require an end to its operations, provides an opportunity for policymakers to determine whether the enabling legislation should be reauthorized and, if so, in what form. As the sunset approaches, and the mortgage debacle is hopefully behind us, policymakers can decide whether further support for the mortgage market is required, and which organizational form is most suitable. If they decided to wind up two government corporations at the end of five years, policymakers would address both the capacity and the life-cycle disadvantages that can otherwise accompany the creation of wholly owned government corporations. Having a five year sunset period would allow the wholly owned government corporations to provide support for 154 the mortgage market at a critical time. The experience of the Resolution Trust Corporation (“RTC”) indicates how a temporary government corporation can develop the capacity to 153 Thomas H. Stanton, Strengthening Government’s Ability to Deal With the Financial Crisis IBM CENTER FOR THE BUSINESS OF GOVERNMENT (2009) [hereinafter Stanton, Strengthening Government’s Ability], at 13, available at http://www.businessofgovernment.org/pdfs/StantonFinancial.pdf. (discussing FHA’s need for enhanced capacity). 154 As GSEs, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in 2009 fund almost three quarters of new residential mortgage originations. See, e.g., Lockhart, supra note 19, at 10. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 259 deal with complex financial issues. It does this by attracting high-quality talent that might not contemplate a longer term career in government.155 The RTC was impressive in the way that it evolved constant improvements in its approach to its mission.156 Even though the Congress could allow one or both of the government corporations to sunset at the end of their charter terms, this is not a foregone conclusion. The continuation of a government corporation could appeal to some policymakers, for example because of the ability to use revenues from mortgage operations to support affordable housing.157 In 1996, the General Accounting Office undertook a study to examine the consequences for the housing market if Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac ceased to operate as firms with any government backing at all. The GAO concluded that the effects would be limited: Privatization would likely change the behavior of market participants and increase average interest rates on fixedrate, single-family mortgages within an average range of about 15 to 35 basis points. However, privatization would not mean the end of the secondary mortgage market, a return to regional disparities in mortgage interest rates that were not based on differences in risk, or a lack of mortgage credit in the economy during parts of the business cycle. It would probably mean that mortgage rates would increase in areas with higher risks, for houses with higher loan-to-value ratios, and in 155 Accord Stanton, supra note 6, at 636 (“Life cycle is also an issue. After some years the government corporations could ‘ossify,’ i.e., begin to display some of the kinds of bureaucratic infirmities that FHA (for example) has manifested in recent years.”). 156 See, e.g., Thomas H. Stanton, Lessons Learned: Obtaining Value From Federal Asset Sales, 23 PUB. BUDGETING & FIN. 22 (2003). 157 Section 1131 of HERA, Pub. L. 110–289, established a Housing Trust Fund that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac would fund with contributions. It would be possible to build such an affordable housing program into a government corporation that serves the mortgage market. See supra note 6, at 636. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 260 periods of high mortgage demand.158 Just as one must question whether a GSE or other private institution is properly manageable once it funds, say, a trillion dollars of mortgages,159 one must also question whether managers of wholly owned government corporations will be up to the task. As a matter of protecting taxpayers from excessive financial risk it would be prudent to limit the size of both public and private institutions that provide financial support to the mortgage market. One clear lesson of the current debacle is that it is risky to maintain immense financial institutions of any kind over the long term.160 One possible way would be to use a government corporation to provide government support for limited purposes, such as a 30-year fixed-rate mortgage for selected borrowers such as firsttime homebuyers. Alternatively, concern about size and risk could lead policymakers to sunset the government corporations after the mortgage market is back on its feet. In either event, the model of the wholly owned government corporation would 158 U.S. General Accounting Office, Housing Enterprises: Potential Impacts of Severing Government Sponsorship, GGD-96-120, May 1996, at 70. A “basis point” is one-one-hundredth of a percentage point. 159 Economist Joseph Stiglitz makes this point about banks: [T]he problem of too-big-to-fail institutions remains. There are but two solutions: breaking up the institutions or regulating them heavily. For reasons that I will make clear, we need to do both. The only justification for allowing these huge institutions to continue is that there are significant economies of scope or scale that otherwise would be lost. I have seen no evidence to that effect . . . we have little to lose, and much to gain, by breaking up these behemoths, which are not just too big to fail but also too big to save and too big to manage. Too Big to Fail or Too Big to Save? Examining the Systematic Threats of Large Financial Institutions: Hearing Before the Joint Economic Committee, 111th Cong. 25–26 (2009) (statement of Joseph Stiglitz, 2001 Nobel Prize Recipient & Professor, Columbia University), available at http://jec.senate. gov/index.cfm?FuseAction=Hearings.HearingsCalendar (follow “April 21st—Too Big to Fail or Too Big to Save?” hyperlink; then follow “Joseph Stiglitz” hyperlink). 160 See id. STANTON 2D REVISION.DOC 5/8/2010 4:06 PM FAILURE OF FANNIE MAE AND FREDDIE MAC 261 remain available when needed to provide government support for the mortgage market in the event of any future crisis. CONCLUSION: USE THE FORMER GSES EXTENSIVELY AT FIRST AND THEN FOR MORE LIMITED SUPPORT OF THE MORTGAGE MARKET The government-sponsored enterprise has outlived its usefulness as an instrument of government policy. While other financial institutions have also shown vulnerability, the GSE appears to be especially prone to dominating and ultimately evading any reasonable accountability structure. GSEs are simply too powerful for their own good. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, now demonstrably insolvent, should be placed into receivership and turned into wholly owned government corporations that could sunset after perhaps five years. As such they could support the mortgage market, not only through their access to government funding, but also by imposing rules for consumer and investor protection, capital requirements on mortgage market participants, and other protective measures that policymakers could apply to the rest of the housing finance system. Also, they could help to shore up potentially vulnerable government agencies such as the FHA that are playing increasingly important roles in the mortgage market. After that, when circumstances have improved, policymakers can decide whether the needs of the housing market should be served by a government corporation, and how to shape that government corporation to address those needs. Especially for the next few years, but also potentially for the longer term, the wholly owned government corporation is an organizational form that offers great promise as a source of support for the mortgage market. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION IN THE SUBPRIME MORTGAGE MARKET: PROPOSALS FOR FAIR LENDING REFORM By Winnie F. Taylor* INTRODUCTION Lending discrimination has been a national problem for decades. Before Congress enacted the Equal Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA) in 1974 to combat it, lenders routinely denied credit to potential borrowers because of their race, gender, age, marital status and other personal characteristics unrelated to creditworthiness standards.1 For instance, some creditors based their lending decisions on stereotypical assumptions about whether women in certain age groups would have children or return to work after childbirth.2 Others excluded minority communities from their lending areas by literally drawing red lines on maps around neighborhoods where mostly African Americans and Hispanics resided.3 The ECOA is a fair lending law that proscribes lending practices that impede credit opportunities for women, racial minorities and others who have * Professor of Law, Brooklyn Law School. I am grateful to Bethany Walsh, Dylan Gordon, and Adrienne Valdez for their helpful research assistance. I also thank the Brooklyn Law School faculty research fund for its support. 1 See Winnie F. Taylor, Meeting the Equal Credit Opportunity Act’s Specificity Requirement: Judgmental and Statistical Scoring Systems, 29 BUFF. L. REV. 73, 74–81 (1980). 2 See NATIONAL COMMISSION ON CONSUMER FIN., CONSUMER CREDIT IN THE UNITED STATES, 151, 152–53 (1972). 3 Gene A. Marsh, Lender Liability for Consumer Fraud Practices of Retail Dealers and Home Improvement Contractors, 45 ALA. L. REV. 1, 15 (1993) (discussing historical origin of the term “redlining”). 263 TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 264 historically experienced credit discrimination. Credit discrimination issues have emerged from the rise and fall of the subprime housing market. The problems stem from the race-based practices of overzealous subprime lenders in the selling of home loans. This discriminatory lending behavior is one of many factors that contributed to the market’s collapse. It is therefore imperative that policy makers concerned about preventing another crisis consider the impact that racial discrimination can have on igniting or exacerbating a mortgage lending disaster. Legal scholars and other commentators have highlighted the discriminatory underpinnings of the crisis,4 noting in particular that some subprime lenders aggressively targeted minority neighborhoods for the purpose of making unaffordable home loans that were destined for delinquency, default, and foreclosure.5 Because of these and other abusive lending tactics, racial minorities received the lion’s share of subprime loans during the housing boom that preceded the crisis.6 After the bubble burst, massive foreclosures followed with a disproportionate share concentrated in minority communities. Consequently, these communities experienced the brunt of the devastation that resulted from the subprime 4 See Raymond H. Brescia, Subprime Communities: Reverse Redlining, the Fair Housing Act and Emerging Issues in Litigation Regarding the Subprime Mortgage Crisis, 2 ALB. GOV’T L. REV. 164 (2009); Brian Gilmore et al., The Nightmare on Main Street for African-Americans: A Call for a New National Policy Focus on Homeownership, 10 BERKELEY J. AFR.-AM. L. & POL’Y 262, 262–65 (2008) (discussing the impact of racial discrimination on the housing crisis). 5 Linda E. Fisher, Target Marketing of Subprime Loans: Racialized Consumer Fraud & Reverse Redlining, 18 J.L. & POL’Y __ (2009). 6 DEBBIE GRUENSTEIN BOCIAN ET AL., CTR. FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, UNFAIR LENDING: THE EFFECT OF RACE AND ETHNICITY ON THE PRICE OF SUBPRIME MORTGAGES (2006), available at http://www.responsiblelending. org/mortgage-lending/research-analysis/rr011-Unfair_Lending-0506.pdf; Christopher Mayer & Karen Pence, Subprime Mortgages: What, Where, and to Whom 2 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 14083, 2007) (discussing subprime loan originations in 2005 and concluding that subprime mortgages during this time period were concentrated in locations with high proportions of black and Hispanic residents). TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 265 “meltdown.”7 Some creditors use unscrupulous marketing and underwriting practices that earn them the label “predatory lenders.”8 Among these lenders are “equal opportunity abusers,” that is, creditors who indiscriminately mistreat minority and non-minority borrowers. Others engage in race-based lending practices that are not only abusive but also illegal under the ECOA. For example, two loan originators employed by a major bank with a significant subprime department before the mortgage market collapsed, described in affidavits how the bank solicited African American customers and charged them more than necessary for mortgage loans because of their race.9 These former bank employees also reported how African American customers were 7 See Matthew Price, Baltimore’s Tale of Sub-prime Woe, BBC NEWS, June 28, 2009, http://news.bbc.co.uk/go/pr/fr/-/2/hi/business/8118376.stm (describing the devastation to the Baltimore community). 8 The term “predatory lending” describes various onerous lending practices, which are often targeted at vulnerable populations. Predatory lending has been defined as a syndrome of abusive loan terms or practices that involve one or more of the following five problems: (1) loans structured to result in seriously disproportionate net harm to borrowers; (2) harmful rent-seeking; (3) loans involving fraud or deceptive practices; (4) other forms of lack of transparency in loans that are not actionable as fraud; and (5) loans that require borrowers to waive meaningful legal redress. See Kathleen C. Engel & Patricia A. McCoy, A Tale of Three Markets: The Law and Economics of Predatory Lending, 80 TEX. L. REV. 1255, 1259–1261 (2002). 9 See affidavit of Tony Paschal, an employee of Wells Fargo, describing practices where employees engaged in marketing specifically targeted at minorities, even going as far as printing out flyers in what they referred to as the “African American” language. Affidavit of Tony Paschal at ¶ 11, Mayor of Baltimore v. Wells Fargo, No. 1:08-cv-00062 (D. Md. June 3, 2009). Another employee described practices where Wells Fargo employees would push subprime loans onto minority customers who were eligible for the lower priced prime rates by deceptive practices ranging from convincing people it was the only way to get the paperwork finished quickly to offering a donation to the church of the customers’ choice. Affidavit of Elizabeth Jacobson at ¶ 12, Mayor of Baltimore v. Wells Fargo, No. 1:08-cv-00062 (D. Md. June 3, 2009). This same employee testified that once she received a referral for a customer, she was only permitted to offer them a subprime loan, even if they were eligible for a prime loan. Id. at ¶ 3. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 266 sometimes steered to subprime loans10 even though such customers qualified for less expensive prime loans.11 The ECOA specifically prohibits disparate treatment on the basis of race.12 This Article proposes action the federal government should take to better protect minority consumers in the subprime market from discriminatory lending practices. First, more impact litigation is needed to encourage compliance with the ECOA and to generate sanctions for subprime creditors who violate fair lending laws. Second, current fair lending laws and regulations designed to ferret out creditors who discriminate on the basis of race need to be revised to better assist federal prosecutors in their litigation efforts. As explained more fully below, claims of racial discrimination in mortgage credit are not new; however, the context of the problem has changed. Initially, the primary concern was denial of home loans to residents of minority communities.13 Today, the dominant concern is excessive bad credit in these communities that is perversely tied to mortgage lenders who intentionally made improvident loans.14 As creditors become more creative in devising discriminatory practices, the 10 A “subprime loan” is a loan that features higher costs than a prime loan, both upfront and throughout the life of the loan. The defining characteristic of the subprime mortgage is the higher interest rate it carries over a prime loan. See Michael Aleo & Pablo Svirsky, Foreclosure Fallout: The Banking Industry’s Attack on Disparate Impact Race Discrimination Claims Under the Fair Housing Act and the Equal Credit Opportunity Act, 18 B.U. PUB. INT. L.J. 1, 5 (2008) (discussing subprime loans). The higher rates are presumably to compensate lenders for the added risks associated with lending to borrowers with weaker credit histories. See ALLEN J. FISHBEIN & PATRICK WOODALL, SUBPRIME LOCATIONS: PATTERNS OF GEOGRAPHIC DISPARITY IN SUBPRIME LENDING 1 (2006), available at www.consumerfed.org/pdfs/SubprimeLocationsStudy090506.pdf. 11 Prime loans are loans with interest rates and fees that conventional banks charge their best customers. See CAL. REINVESTMENT COALITION ET AL, PAYING MORE FOR THE AMERICAN DREAM, A MULTI-STATE ANALYSIS OF HIGHER COST PURCHASE LENDING, app. (2007), available at http://www.calreinvest.org/system/assets/47.pdf. 12 See Equal Credit Opportunity Act, 15 U.S.C. §1691 (2006). 13 See supra note 3. 14 See supra text accompanying note 5. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 267 federal response should include enhancement of fair lending enforcement and stronger consumer protection laws. In exploring the proposals presented herein, the first part of this Article emphasizes the importance of government litigation as a means of combating lending discrimination in the subprime housing market. For almost two decades, ECOA enforcement authorities have litigated race-based mortgage lending claims. This section reviews that litigation and argues for more federal prosecution of subprime lenders that discriminate on the basis of race. The second part argues for regulatory reform. Specifically, this part proposes amending Regulation C,15 which implements 16 the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA), by adding credit scores to the information subprime lenders must report to federal regulatory agencies regarding their home mortgage lending experience. Currently, certain lenders must collect and report demographic and pricing data that federal officials analyze to determine if discriminatory lending patterns exist that violate fair lending laws. Including credit score data in the analysis would enhance the ability of these officials to make this determination. As explained in greater detail in Part II below, adding credit risk information to the HMDA reporting requirements might cause some lenders to make fewer subprime loans, especially those concerned about greater exposure to lawsuits and more regulatory scrutiny. However, if subprime lenders cut back significantly in making mortgage loans, credit-impaired borrowers, who are their primary customers, will be further 17 limited in home financing options. To address this concern, I 15 12 C.F.R. § 203 (2009). 12 U.S.C. §§ 2801–2810 (2006). 17 The subprime lender specializes in issuing high-interest mortgages to families with few credit options. See Elizabeth Warren, The Economics of Race: When Making It to the Middle Is Not Enough, 61 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 1777, 1792–94 (2004) (discussing the history of subprime lending). Most subprime refinance borrowers use the collateral in their homes for debt consolidation and other consumer credit purposes. See FISHBEIN & WOODALL, supra note 10, at 1 (discussing subprime borrowers who refinance home loans). 16 TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 268 argue that the federal government should provide funds to credit unions for the purpose of increasing their subprime lending. This public funding proposal is attractive for several reasons. First, if some subprime lenders reduce mortgage credit because the Federal Reserve Board (FRB) adds credit scores to their HMDA reporting requirements, credit unions may be able to fill the void by expanding their subprime lending to more qualified, higher-risk borrowers in under-served communities. Given their non-profit, quasi-governmental status, credit unions are unlikely to reduce subprime mortgage lending because of a new credit score reporting requirement.18 Second, expanding the credit union subprime market would provide potential borrowers with viable alternatives to abusive home mortgage providers. Third, such expansion would provide competition to predatory subprime lenders. By focusing on remedies and strategies for combating the racial discrimination problem in subprime lending, this Article brings issues of race and ethnicity to the forefront of the mortgage crisis where they belong. Developing effective responses to prevent its reoccurrence demands consideration of all factors that led to the market’s demise, especially those indicative of unlawful conduct. I. IMPACT LITIGATION AND ACCOUNTABILITY Congress gave ECOA enforcement authority to the FRB, the Department of Justice (DOJ), the Federal Trade Commission 19 (FTC), and a number of other federal agencies. Claims of 18 See Ronald H. Silverman, Toward Curbing Predatory Lending, 122 BANKING L.J. 483 (2005); see also infra text accompanying note 107. 19 Enforcement authority under the ECOA is divided between federal agencies. The U.S Department of Justice may initiate a lawsuit under the ECOA where it believes a creditor has engaged in a pattern or practice of discrimination. With respect to claims against national banks, and Federal branches, enforcement authority is with the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC); for claims against member banks of the Federal Reserve System (other than national banks), and commercial lending companies owned or controlled by foreign banks, enforcement authority is with the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; for claims against banks TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 269 racial discrimination in the subprime mortgage market present the latest regulatory challenge to these authorities. In addition to investigating and examining creditors for fair lending compliance, government agencies should use litigation vigorously to address discrimination claims. Their sustained litigation efforts will likely encourage fair lending compliance by sending a clear message to the lending industry that ECOA violators will be relentlessly pursued, prosecuted, and held accountable for engaging in unlawful conduct. The DOJ and the FTC already have experience litigating ECOA claims similar to many of those that have emerged from the mortgage crisis, including those involving discriminatory pricing. Some of their groundbreaking cases are summarized in the next section. All of the cases were settled. Nevertheless, these cases helped establish novel lending discrimination theories20 and demonstrate that litigation can be an effective means of combating racial discrimination in mortgage lending. To achieve this end, litigation efforts must be relentless. A. Redlining At the federal level, efforts to eliminate home mortgage discrimination have been ongoing for almost two decades. In 1992, the DOJ filed its first ECOA mortgage-lending lawsuit against a Georgia bank. The complaint charged the bank with “redlining,” that is, refusing to make loans in certain geographical areas because of the racial composition of its 21 residents. Specifically, DOJ attorneys alleged that Decatur Federal Savings & Loan “devised ways to avoid dealing with insured by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (other than members of the Federal Reserve System) and insured State branches of foreign banks, enforcement authority is with the Board of Directors of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation; for claims against credit unions enforcement authority resides with the Administrator of the National Credit Union Administration. See Equal Credit Opportunity Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1691c(a)(1)(A)–(C) (2006). 20 See NATIONAL CONSUMER LAW CENTER, THE CREDIT AND SALES LEGAL PRACTICE SERIES § 12.4.1 (4th ed. 2005). 21 See supra note 3. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 270 African Americans in the Atlanta area and avoided making mortgage loans in black communities.”22 To support the claim that Decatur Federal intentionally denied banking services to African Americans, the complaint further alleged that none of the bank’s 48 branch offices were located in predominately African American neighborhoods.23 The consent decree that settled the case required the bank to pay $1 million to compensate 48 rejected credit applicants and to take a series of corrective measures to ensure compliance with the ECOA, including opening up a branch office in a predominately black neighborhood.24 Since 1992, the DOJ has filed and settled a myriad of redlining lawsuits against banks and other financial institutions. In one such case involving a bank in the District of Columbia, DOJ attorneys alleged that Chevy Chase Bank refused to market mortgage loans in predominately African American communities in Washington, D.C., because of the racial identity of those neighborhoods.25 As it did in Decatur, the DOJ’s litigation strategy included focusing on the location of bank branch offices to support its contention that the bank intentionally excluded blacks from receiving its mortgage lending services. Accordingly, the complaint alleged that 70 of the 74 Chevy Chase branch offices were located in predominately white communities.26 The settlement agreement required the bank to pay $11 million to establish a special loan program so that mortgage-lending services could be provided to the neglected areas. The agreement also required the bank to open up branch 27 offices in minority neighborhoods. Similarly, the DOJ sued Albank for redlining in violation of 22 Complaint at ¶¶ 8–16, United States v. Decatur Fed. Sav. & Loan Assoc., No. 92-CV-2198 (N.D. Ga. 1992). 23 Id. at ¶¶ 4, 9. 24 Consent Decree at ¶¶ 2–48, Decatur, No. 92-CV-2198 (N.D. Ga. 1992). 25 Complaint at ¶ 12, United States v. Chevy Chase Fed. Sav. Bank, No. 94-CV-01829 (D.D.C. 1994). 26 Id. at ¶ 13. 27 Consent Decree, Chevy Chase, No. 94-CV-01829. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 271 the ECOA. In this 1997 case, DOJ attorneys contended that the bank refused to take mortgage loan applications from areas in Connecticut and Westchester County, New York, with significant minority populations. Further, the government attorneys claimed that the bank could provide no reason for carving out minority communities from its lending areas.28 The consent decree that ended this litigation required the bank to provide $55 million in loans at below market rates to the communities that it refused to service previously and to implement a non-discriminatory lending policy.29 More recently, the DOJ prosecuted two mid-western banks for redlining. In 2004, the agency resolved a lawsuit it filed against First American Bank. The DOJ attorneys claimed that the bank unlawfully failed to market its mortgage credit and other lending products to predominately minority neighborhoods in the Chicago and Kankakee, Illinois, metropolitan areas.30 Additionally, the prosecutors alleged that of the nearly $288 million in single family residential real estate loans that the bank funded between 1999 and 2001, only 4.5% went to properties located in minority census tracts.31 The terms of the consent order required First American to open four new full-service branch offices, three of which had to be located in majority African American census tracts in the Chicago area and one in a majority Hispanic census tract. Further, it required the bank to invest $5 million in a special financing program for residents and businesses in the minority communities of the Chicago/Kankakee areas.32 In 2006, DOJ attorneys filed the other mid-western bank case and subsequently resolved redlining allegations against 28 Complaint at ¶ 14, United States v. Albank, FSB, No. 97-CV-1206 (N.D.N.Y 1997). 29 Consent Decree at § III(1), Albank, No. 97-CV-1206. 30 Id. (consent decree). Complaint at ¶¶ 17–21, United States v. First Am. Bank, No. 04-CV-4585 (N.D. Ill. July 13, 2004) [hereinafter First American Consent Decree]. The DOJ’s complaint alleged that all but four of the bank’s 34 branches were located in a minority area. Id. at ¶ 15. 31 Id. at ¶ 28. 32 First American Consent Decree, supra note 30, at § III. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 272 Centier Bank in Indiana. At the time of the litigation, Centier Bank was one of the largest residential lenders in the Gary, Indiana, metropolitan area.33 The complaint alleged that the bank avoided serving the mortgage credit needs of neighborhoods where the majority of the residents are African American or Hispanic, especially in the cities of Gary, East Chicago, and Hammond.34 The settlement agreement that ended this lawsuit required the bank to open or acquire at least two full service offices within designated African American and Hispanic areas. It also required the bank to provide the same services offered at its majority white suburban locations to all branches regardless of their location. Further, the bank had to invest a minimum of $3.5 million in special financing programs for residential and small business loans.35 The above redlining cases highlight the historical lack of conventional mortgage lending sources in minority communities and the efforts of government attorneys to remove racial barriers to minority homeownership and residential refinancing. They also demonstrate how racial discrimination can create a dual system of mortgage lending that can lock minority borrowers out of lower-cost mortgage credit that conventional lenders typically provide. When these lenders refuse to lend in minority neighborhoods, a void is created that abusive lenders fill by charging excessive rates and imposing other unfavorable loan terms. Thus, conventional lenders can play a significant role in making minority borrowers especially vulnerable to predatory subprime lenders. To prevent such exploitation, ECOA enforcement authorities must remain vigilant in combating redlining. B. Reverse Redlining In contrast to redlining, the claims of racial discrimination in 33 Complaint at ¶¶ 3–6, United States v. Centier Bank, No. 06-CV-344 (N.D. Ind. Oct. 13, 2006). 34 Id. at ¶ 10. 35 Consent Order at ¶ 23, Centier Bank, No. 06-CV-344. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 273 mortgage lending that emerged from the subprime crisis focus on an abundance of mortgage credit in minority neighborhoods; however, this credit has been notoriously burdensome. These “reverse redlining”36 complaints allege that some predatory subprime lenders target minority neighborhoods for the purpose of making mortgage loans that are saddled with unfavorable terms, especially price inequities. Although federal prosecutors began litigating reverse redlining claims more than a decade before the subprime crisis, the foreclosure epidemic that has caused devastation to many minority neighborhoods37 is likely to precipitate a notable increase in the filing of these cases. Importantly, the government’s reverse redlining cases have created a template that private litigants can use to structure arguments for proving disparate impact38 and disparate treatment39 lending discrimination claims. 36 “Reverse redlining” is the practice of extending credit on unfair terms to specific geographic areas due to the income, race or ethnicity of its residents. Assoc. Home Equity Servs., Inc. v. Troup, 778 A.2d 529, 537 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 2001) (citations omitted). 37 See Fisher, supra note 5. 38 Disparate impact discrimination occurs when creditors use neutral policies or practices that have a disproportionate adverse affect on persons in the ECOA protected classes. This framework for proving lending discrimination has a burden-shifting approach. The first step under this approach requires the plaintiff to prove that a creditor practice or policy created a disparity on an ECOA prohibited basis. If the plaintiff establishes this prima facie case, the burden shifts to the creditor to prove that the policy is justified by a business necessity. At the final stage, the plaintiff prevails if there is sufficient evidence that an alternative policy or practice could serve the creditor’s same business purpose with less discriminatory effect. See Griggs v. Duke Power Company, 401 U.S. 424 (1971); Albemarle Paper Company v. Moody, 422 U.S. 405 (1975) (discussing the approach in the context of employment discrimination); see also infra notes 70–74 and accompanying text. 39 Disparate treatment discrimination occurs when creditors treat some borrowers or potential borrowers less favorably than others because of ECOA protected class characteristics such as race or sex. Under this theory, proof of the lender’s discriminatory intent is crucial. In employment law, burdenshifting approach is used to prove disparate treatment cases. See McDonnell Douglas Corp. v. Green, 411 U.S. 792, 804–806 (1973). TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 274 In 1996, the DOJ brought a reverse redlining lawsuit against Long Beach Mortgage Company challenging its mortgage pricing policies. Long Beach is a subprime mortgage affiliate of Washington Mutual Savings Association.40 The complaint alleged that the mortgage company directed its marketing efforts primarily toward persons and neighborhoods of color that lending officials believed might be susceptible to higher prices.41 Also, DOJ attorneys contended that the mortgage company’s loan originators typically emphasized low monthly payment amounts when discussing loan prices with minority borrowers rather than interest rates, points, and annual percentages rates.42 Further, the complaint asserted that Long Beach allowed both its employee loan officers and its independent loan brokers the discretion to charge subprime mortgage borrowers a commission of up to 12% above the lender’s base price for the loan amount.43 The DOJ attorneys contended that this discretionary pricing policy resulted in disparate treatment of minorities and other borrowers protected under the ECOA. In particular, the DOJ alleged that African American females over the age of 55 were 2.6 times more likely than white males under the age of 56 to be charged fees and points under Long Beach’s lending policies.44 In the mortgage lending industry, pricing disparities often arise from “overages,” that is, discretionary authority of employees or brokers who originate loans to charge higher rates than the lender’s set rate.45 Because they usually receive 40 Some major banks engage in subprime mortgage lending through subsidiary companies. For instance, NationsCredit and EquiCredit are Bank of America’s subprime affiliates and Citigroup is Citibank’s subprime lending subsidiary. 41 Complaint at ¶ 18, United States v. Long Beach Mortgage Co., No. 96 Civ. 6159 (C.D. Cal. Sept. 5, 1996) [hereinafter Long Beach Complaint]. 42 Id. 43 Id. at ¶ 15. 44 Id. at ¶ 19. 45 “Overage” or “yield spread,” refers to the practice of allowing loan personnel to charge customers a higher interest rate than the lender’s base or minimum rate. As an incentive for bringing in loans at a higher rate, lenders frequently share the overage with the loan originator. See NATIONAL TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 275 additional compensation when borrowers agree to pay prices above the lender’s set rate, loan originators have an incentive to make loans at the highest rate possible. In Long Beach, the government claimed that the discretionary pricing policy resulted in disparate treatment of minorities and other borrowers protected under the ECOA.46 Moreover, the DOJ claimed that the mortgage company was liable not only for the discriminatory pricing of its loan officers but also for that of the independent brokers. The DOJ concluded that the lender should be liable for the brokers’ conduct because the mortgage company was ultimately responsible for underwriting the loans and hiring the brokers.47 In settlement, Long Beach agreed to pay $3 million to 1,200 borrowers and to spend $1 million on educational programs.48 In 1996, the DOJ again confronted the issue of discriminatory pricing in a reverse redlining case when it prosecuted two mortgage companies. The complaints alleged that loan officers at Fleet Mortgage Company in Brooklyn, New York, and Huntington Mortgage Company in Cleveland, Ohio, charged African American and Hispanic borrowers higher upfront fees for mortgages than they charged similarly situated white borrowers.49 Further, the complaint alleged that the higher CONSUMER LAW CENTER, THE CREDIT AND SALES LEGAL PRACTICES SERIES § 12.4.3.9 (3d ed. 2002). 46 Long Beach Complaint, supra note 41, at ¶ 24. 47 Settlement Agreement, United States v. Long Beach Mortgage Co., No. 96-CV-6159 (C.D. Cal. Sept. 5, 2009) [hereinafter Long Beach Settlement]. Also, the role that independent mortgage brokers played in the subprime crisis is being scrutinized with an eye toward regulation and oversight. It is the alleged abusive conduct of brokers that has led to many proposals for regulatory reform in the subprime mortgage market. See Alan M. White, The Case for Banning Subprime Mortgages, 77 U. CIN. L. REV. 617 (2008); Lloyd T. Wilson, Jr., Sometimes Less is More: Utility, Preemption, and Hermeneutical Criticisms of Proposed Federal Regulation of Mortgage Brokers, 59 S.C. L. REV. 61 (2007). 48 Long Beach Settlement, supra note 47. 49 Complaint at ¶ 9, United States v. Fleet Mortgage Corp., No. 96-CV2279 (E.D.N.Y. May 7, 1996) [hereinafter Fleet Complaint]; Complaint at ¶ 9, 12, 14, United States v. Huntington Mortgage Co., No. 95-CV-2211 TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 276 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY prices, which resulted from a compensation incentive program similar to the one in Long Beach, could not have occurred by chance and were unrelated to the qualifications of the minority borrowers or the risk to the lender.50 The DOJ attorneys did not challenge the legality of the employee/broker incentive program. Instead, they claimed that the two mortgage companies illegally used the program to extract higher prices from minorities because of their race.51 Private litigants have followed the lead of DOJ attorneys in making ECOA price discrimination claims against subprime lenders with broker/employee incentive programs like that in Long Beach.52 In another high-impact, reverse-redlining lawsuit, three government agencies jointly prosecuted a major subprime lender. The three agencies—the U.S. Attorney for the Eastern District of New York (DOJ), the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD), and the FTC—filed a reverse redlining lawsuit against Delta Funding Corporation. At the time of this litigation, most of Delta’s business was concentrated in the minority residential areas of Brooklyn and Queens, New York.53 Among other allegations, the government claimed that Delta violated the ECOA by granting loans with higher broker fees to African American women than those of similarly situated white men, by allowing unreasonable broker fees, by engaging in asset-based lending, by paying kickbacks to brokers to induce them to refer loan applicants to Delta, and by approving loans without regard for the borrower’s ability to repay.54 Further, the complaint alleged that Delta targeted minority neighborhoods (N.D. Ohio Oct. 18, 1995) [hereinafter Huntington Complaint]. 50 Fleet Complaint, supra note 49, at ¶ 10; Huntington Complaint, supra note 49, at ¶¶ 12–14. 51 See Fleet Complaint, supra note 49, at ¶ 11; Huntington Complaint, supra note 49, at ¶ 15. 52 See Miller v. Countrywide Bank, N.A., 571 F. Supp. 2d 251, 253 (D. Mass. 2008); Garcia v. Country Wide Fin. Corp., No. 07-CV-1161, 2008 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 106675, at *2 (C.D. Cal. Jan. 17, 2008). 53 Complaint at ¶ 8, United States v. Delta Funding Corp., No. 00-CV01872 (E.D.N.Y. 2000). 54 Id. at ¶¶ 12, 14–15, 17–19. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 277 with abusive practices, thereby placing borrowers thousands of dollars in debt and exposing them to unwarranted risk of default and foreclosure.55 The complaint described a number of Delta’s victims as African American widows living in Brooklyn who had little or no outstanding debt before refinancing their mortgages at prices they could not afford.56 The settlement agreement that ended the case required Delta to provide monetary relief of up to $12 million to victims of its lending practices.57 In 2008, the FTC filed an ECOA action individually against Gateway Funding Diversified Mortgage Services Corporation and its general partner, Gateway Funding.58 Among the FTC’s allegations was the claim that Gateway used discriminatory pricing practices in both prime and subprime mortgage loans that resulted in African American and Hispanic customers being charged higher interest rates and up-front fees than white customers.59 The settlement required Gateway to pay $2.9 million, however, all but $200,000 was suspended because of Gateway’s inability to pay.60 C. Establishing ECOA Precedents Private litigants have also filed reverse redlining lawsuits against subprime lenders with allegations similar to those in the above government cases.61 As these cases work their way up 55 Id. at ¶ 17. Press Release, Dep’t of Justice, Delta Funding Corporation Settles U.S. Charges for Fair Lending and Consumer Law (Mar. 30, 2000), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/opa/pr/2000/March/154cr.htm. 57 Settlement Agreement at § 5, Delta, No. 00-CV-01872. 58 Complaint, FTC v. Gateway Funding Diversified Mortgage Servs., L.P., No. 08-CV-5805 (E.D. Pa. Dec. 17, 2008). 59 Id. at ¶ 18. 60 Final Judgment at § VI(A), Gateway, No. 08-CV-5805. 61 See, e.g., NAACP v. Ameriquest Mortgage Co., No. 07-CV-0794 (C.D. Cal. Jan. 12, 2009) (order denying defendants’ motion to dismiss). The NAACP alleged disparate impact and disparate treatment discrimination in violation of ECOA. 56 TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 278 through the courts, they may establish much needed precedent on the legal issues surrounding the targeting of minority neighborhoods. Precedential value could also come if government reverse redlining lawsuits lead to full-fledged litigation instead of settlement. Although the advantages of settlement (e.g., lower cost, certainty of outcome, expeditiousness) are important, it would also be tremendously beneficial for courts to decide whether the government’s redlining and reverse redlining claims are meritorious. Established precedent can reveal gaps in the current laws and provide guidance regarding appropriate ways to fill them, such as whether new legislation is needed to further federal fair lending policy objectives. There are additional advantages to having judicial opinions in reverse redlining cases. For instance, victims likely receive a psychological benefit when courts find lenders liable for discrimination. This benefit is absent when cases are settled because settlement agreements contain no admission to or finding of illegal conduct. Also, it would be helpful to know how courts would impose damages against subprime lenders found liable for targeting minority neighborhoods and engaging in discriminatory pricing practices in violation of the ECOA. The settlement agreements mentioned above require lenders to pay millions of dollars to compensate consumers and establish funding for various programs.62 These amounts seem to reflect both actual and punitive damages. However, if ECOA claims are fully litigated and lenders are subsequently found liable for discrimination, it is unclear whether courts could award similar damages. Currently, ECOA violators are subject to civil liability for actual and punitive damages in individual and class actions. Liability for punitive damages is limited to $10,000 in individual actions and the lesser of $500,000 or one percent of the 63 creditor’s net worth in class actions. In determining the amount of punitive damages, the Act requires courts to consider, among 62 63 See, e.g., supra text accompanying notes 48, 57, and 60. 15 U.S.C. § 1691e (2006). TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 279 other relevant factors, the amount of any actual damages awarded, the frequency and persistence of failures of compliance by the creditor, the resources of the creditor, the number of persons adversely affected, and the extent to which the creditor’s failure of compliance was intentional.64 Although courts may find that millions of dollars in punitive damages should be imposed against lenders in some reverse redlining cases, it is unclear whether the $500,000 statutory ceiling will preclude such awards in actions brought by federal prosecutors. In private lawsuits, the ECOA specifically caps punitive damages at $500,000. The statute is silent, however, on whether the cap applies when administrative agencies successfully sue lenders. The ECOA’s statutory language merely states that the agencies may recover “relief as may be appropriate,” including actual and punitive damages.65 The Federal Reserve Board, which implements the ECOA through Regulation B,66 should clarify whether punitive damages in administrative agency actions can exceed $500,000. If the cap does apply, Congress should amend the ECOA to increase it or allow judges to decide each case without a cap. The $500,000 ceiling on punitive damages is insufficient to punish subprime lenders who egregiously fail to comply with the ECOA by targeting minority neighborhoods for unaffordable loans that are likely to lead to foreclosure. Also, this amount is inadequate to deter other subprime lenders from devastating minority communities by engaging in reverse redlining lending practices. To determine an appropriate amount, consideration should be given to a lender’s net assets. For instance, Bank of America’s 67 profits in the first quarter of 2009 were $2.4 billion and Wells Fargo had a 50% surge in net income during the same period, 68 exceeding more than a billion dollars. Also, during the second 64 Id. Id. at § 1691e(h). 66 12 C.F.R. § 202 (2003). 67 Dan Fitzpatrick, For B of A, a $4.2 Billion Profit Isn’t a Fix, WALL ST. J., Apr. 21, 2009, at C1. 68 Matthias Rieker & Damian Paletta, Banks Get Boost from Wells Fargo, WALL ST. J., Apr. 21, 2009, at C1. 65 TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 280 quarter of 2009, the profits for JP Morgan/Chase Bank were $2.7 billion.69 With quarterly profits like these, a $500,000 penalty for an ECOA violation is grossly inadequate as a punishment or a deterrent. D. Litigation Challenges In Pursuing Reverse Redlining Cases Government attorneys who litigate reverse redlining claims on the merits may have difficulty proving some of their allegations in court. For instance, claims that certain subprime lending practices adversely impact people and communities of color present litigation challenges. The primary challenge stems from the uncertainty about whether ECOA plaintiffs can use the disparate impact theory to prove their lending discrimination claims. As mentioned previously, disparate impact discrimination occurs when a lender applies a neutral practice equally to credit applicants but the practice has a disproportionate adverse effect on applicants from the ECOA protected groups.70 To prove such claims, plaintiffs must demonstrate that there is a significant disparity in outcomes between minorities and similarly situated non-minorities.71 Recently, the United States Supreme Court decided that the disparate impact analytical framework is appropriate to use when proving age discrimination cases.72 However, the Court has not decided whether impact analysis can be used to prove lending discrimination claims. Although most federal courts allow 73 ECOA plaintiffs to use statistical impact proof methods, 69 Robin Sidel, J.P. Morgan Posts $2.7 Billion in Profit, WALL ST. J., July 17, 2009, at C1. 70 See Griggs v. Duke Power Company, 401 U.S. 424 (1971). 71 See supra note 38. 72 See Smith v. City of Jackson, Miss., 544 U.S. 228, 239–240 (2005). 73 See, e.g., Smith v. Chrysler Fin. Co., No. 00-CV-6003, 2003 WL 328719 (D.N.J. 2003) (deciding that the ECOA permits disparate impact theory); Coleman v. General Motor Acceptance Corp., 196 F.R.D. 315 (M.D. Tenn. 2000); Osborne v. Bank of Am., Nat’l Assoc., 234 F. Supp. 2d 804 (M.D. Tenn. 2002). Cf. Latimore v. Citibank Fed. Sav. Bank, 151 F. 3d TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 281 commentators strongly debate whether the Supreme Court would reverse those decisions if given the opportunity.74 Fully litigated reverse redlining lawsuits that use impact proof methods could present the Court with such an opportunity. E. Summary Vigilance in protecting homeowners from lending discrimination not only fosters a fair lending compliance environment, it also promotes public trust. It is therefore especially important for the federal government to prosecute egregious violators of the ECOA. Subprime lenders that cause devastation to individuals because of their race, and communities because of their racial composition, should know that government attorneys will sue them. Such impact litigation will signal to the public and the credit industry that eliminating racial discrimination in mortgage lending is a national priority. II: LEGISLATIVE REFORM: INCREASED ENFORCEMENT AUTHORITY AND HMDA AMENDMENT A. Reporting Credit Score Information Congress enacted HMDA in 1975 due to its concern that disproportionate home ownership among various racial groups might stem from biased lending practices or other discriminatory conduct in the mortgage industry.75 To address this concern, 712 (7th Cir. 1998) (rejecting ECOA disparate impact claim). 74 See, e.g., Peter N. Cubita & Michelle Hartmann, The ECOA Discrimination Proscription and Disparate Impact—Interpreting the Meaning of the Words That Actually Are There, 61 BUS. LAW. 829 (2006). 75 The Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) was enacted by Congress in 1975 and is implemented by the Federal Reserve Board’s Regulation C. This regulation provides the public loan data that can be used to assist in determining whether financial institutions are serving the housing needs of their communities; assisting public officials in distributing publicsector investments so as to attract private investment to areas where it is needed, and in identifying possible discriminatory lending patterns. See FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION, COMPLIANCE HANDBOOK, 9.1, TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 282 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY HMDA requires creditors to collect and report basic attributes of the mortgage applications they receive in metropolitan statistical areas.76 Under Regulation C, which the Federal Reserve Board wrote to implement HMDA, lenders must disclose to federal regulatory agencies and the general public, information regarding the race, ethnicity, sex, and income of mortgage applicants and borrowers.77 In addition to demographic information, Regulation C requires lenders to report certain pricing information.78 Federal officials analyze the HMDA data to see if they identify mortgage lenders with racial or ethnic lending patterns that indicate discrimination in violation of the ECOA or other fair lending laws. Initially, the FRB did not require lenders to report pricing information with other HMDA data. The FRB amended Regulation C in 2002 to add this information because it wanted insight into the possible connection between the cost of mortgage loans and the borrower’s race.79 The pricing information, coupled with HMDA demographic data, informs the FRB of not only who receives mortgage credit, but also who pays the most for it. Pursuant to the loan-pricing reporting requirement, lenders must now report information on “higher-cost” loans. Although both prime and subprime lenders must report the pricing data, this requirement primarily affects subprime lenders since most high-cost loans are made in the subprime market.80 9.2 (2006). 76 12 U.S.C. § 2803(a)(1) (2006). The HMDA requires lenders to use census tracts to capture these data. 77 12 C.F.R. § 203.4(a)(10), (b)(1) (2009). 78 Id. at § 203.4(a)(12)(i). 79 Edward M. Gramlich, Governor, Fed. Reserve Sys., Remarks to the National Association of Real Estate Editors (June 3, 2005). 80 Beginning with 2004 data, lenders are now required to compare the annual percentage rate (APR) on each loan made to the current interest rate on U.S. Treasury securities of the same maturity. If the difference (“spread”) between the loan’s APR and the interest rate on the Treasury securities is three percentage points or more (for a first-lien loan), then the spread for that loan must be reported in the lender’s HMDA data.” CAL. REINVESTMENT COALITION ET AL., supra note 11, app. In the lending industry, such loans are referred to as “higher-cost loans” or “higher-priced loans.” Id. Many TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 283 By all accounts, the addition of pricing information to the HMDA reporting requirements has been a tremendous benefit to ECOA enforcement officials. In recent reports to Congress, the agencies have emphasized the importance of this information to their fair lending enforcement efforts, noting in particular how invaluable it has been in helping to identify lenders that may be engaging in race-based lending practices.81 However, the HMDA data do not include all variables lenders use to set loan prices, such as loan-to value ratios, debtto-income ratios, or credit scores.82 Given this underinclusiveness, the HMDA data are insufficient to determine whether a lender has actually violated the ECOA’s antidiscrimination requirements. Thus, instead of proving discrimination, the data serve as a screening device to identify which lenders should be investigated and further scrutinized for people use the terms “subprime loans” and “higher-cost” loans interchangeably, although there are many subprime loans (subprime because their interest rates and/or fees are greater than those of prime loans) with APRs that are below the HMDA-reporting threshold used to identify “highercost” loans. Id. 81 See, e.g., GRACE CHUNG BECKER, U.S. ATTORNEY GEN., THE ATTORNEY GENERAL’S 2007 ANNUAL REPORT TO CONGRESS PURSUANT TO THE EQUAL CREDIT OPPORTUNITY ACT AMENDMENTS OF 1976 6 (2008), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/crt//housing/documents/ecoa2007.pdf; LORETTA KING, U.S. ATTORNEY GEN., THE ATTORNEY GENERAL’S 2008 ANNUAL REPORT TO CONGRESS PURSUANT TO THE EQUAL CREDIT OPPORTUNITY ACT AMENDMENTS OF 1976 6 (2009), available at http://www. usdoj.gov/crt/housing/documents/ecoa_report_2008.pdf; Rooting Out Discrimination in Mortgage Lending: Using HMDA as a Tool for Fair Lending Enforcement: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Oversight and Investigations of the H. Comm. on Financial Servs., 110th Cong. 38, 42, (2007) (statements of Sandra L. Thompson, Director of the Division of Supervision and Consumer Protection, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation and Calvin R. Hagins, Director of Compliance Policy, Office of the Comptroller of Currency) [hereinafter Rooting Out Discrimination Hearing]. 82 See Robert B. Avery et al., New Information Reported Under HMDA and Its Application in Fair Lending Enforcement, 91 FED. RES. BULL. 344, 385–87 (2005) [hereinafter Avery, New Information]. A credit score is a mechanically determined credit rating that signifies whether an applicant is creditworthy based on key attributes of the applicant and aspects of the credit transaction. See Taylor, supra note 1, at 88. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 284 possible discriminatory conduct.83 In short, HMDA data provide a list of suspects. But the omission of all credit risk criteria from HMDA analyses hinders the data’s effectiveness, even as a screening tool. Lenders can capitalize on this shortcoming. For instance, if HMDA data show significant price disparities along racial lines, the subprime lending industry can point out that the findings are misleading because legitimate credit risk factors that are omitted from the analysis could possibly justify the result. More specifically, lenders can say that credit scores, rather than race or ethnicity, are the cause of the racial disparities. Undoubtedly, credit risk factors can justify racial disparities in the HMDA data of some mortgage lenders and can help to identify others whose disparities result from discriminatory lending practices. Despite this benefit, there are no credit risk data in the HMDA analysis. The absence of such data makes it more difficult to determine which lenders are engaging in illegal conduct, since racial disparities, standing alone, do not prove discrimination. Because credit scores may easily explain the disparities, this credit risk information ought to be included in the HMDA data. The addition of credit score data would permit more nuanced analyses that would reveal more about whether race, credit risk or something else drives the observed differences in the price that people of color pay for mortgage loans.84 Because credit history information will result in an analysis of HMDA data that is more indicative of where fair lending violations are likely to be found, the FRB should require the reporting of credit scores, at least for subprime lenders. More stringent scrutiny of this sector of the home mortgage market is needed because of the serious questions that have emerged regarding the link between the mortgage crisis and 85 discriminatory pricing methods of predatory subprime lenders. 83 Avery et al., supra note 82, at 387. Kathleen Engel & Patricia McCoy, HMDA Reporting of Credit Scores, CREDIT SLIPS, Dec. 12, 2006, http://www.creditslips.org/creditslips/2006/12/ hmda_reporting_.html. 85 See generally Melissa LaVenia, Note, Predatory Lending’s Role in the Subprime Mortgage Crisis, 27 REV. BANKING & FIN. L. 101 (2008) 84 TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 285 Allegations that these lenders targeted minority neighborhoods and intentionally made numerous unaffordable mortgage loans to their residents are among the frequently cited abuses.86 There is public concern that these and other discriminatory lending practices played a significant role in the foreclosure catastrophe that devastated minority neighborhoods after the subprime market collapsed.87 Moreover, for the fifth consecutive year since lenders began reporting pricing information to federal regulators, the HMDA data have indicated that a higher percentage of black and Hispanic borrowers have received highcost home loans than have white borrowers.88 These troubling outcomes reinforce the need for greater scrutiny of the subprime market. By amending Regulation C to require subprime lenders to report credit score information, the FRB and other fair lending enforcement agencies can identify potential ECOA violators more accurately and therefore use their resources more efficiently to investigate subprime creditors for discriminatory lending practices. With a sharper tool to assist in identifying creditors who may be over-charging minorities for home loans, federal agencies will be able to make subprime lenders more accountable for their lending decisions. Banking regulators are apparently aware that credit score data can enhance their fair lending enforcement efforts. During the 2007 Congressional hearings on discrimination in mortgage credit, a representative from the OCC stated that the members of the Federal Financial (analyzing the relationship between predatory lending and foreclosures of subprime mortgages). 86 See, e.g., Rooting Out Discrimination Hearing, supra note 81, at 106– 11. 87 See Fisher, supra note 5. 88 See New Information, supra note 82, at 376–82; Robert Avery et al., Higher Priced Home Lending and the 2005 HMDA Data, 92 FED. RES. BULL. 123, 158–165 (2006) [hereinafter 2005 HMDA Data]; Robert B. Avery et al., The 2006 HMDA Data, 93 FED. RES. BULL. 73, 94–97 (2007) [hereinafter 2006 HMDA Data]; Robert B. Avery et al., The 2007 HMDA Data, 94 FED. RES. BULL. 107, 135–39 (2008) [hereinafter 2007 HMDA Data]. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 286 Institutions Examination Council (FFIEC)89 intended to jointly purchase “an external database of credit scores” to help in the general assessment of fair lending risks.90 Whether the agencies actually purchased the database and precisely how they are using it if they did, is unknown. What seems clear is that ECOA enforcement authorities recognize that credit scores can assist their efforts to combat discrimination in the subprime mortgage market. Thus, the FRB ought to require subprime lenders to report credit scores in addition to their current HMDA data reporting requirements. B. Costs and Benefits Before imposing an additional reporting requirement on subprime lenders, the FRB must weigh the costs and benefits of doing so. On the positive side, the credit risk information would permit federal regulatory agencies to focus their investigations more efficiently when investigating lenders suspected of mixing 91 race and risk in violation of the ECOA. This information may benefit some subprime lenders as well, since the analyzed credit score data could partially explain some racial disparities in pricing. Although these explanations would not be conclusive, they could make some lending patterns with racial disparities look less suspicious.92 89 Federal banking examiners that comprise the FFIEC are the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, the National Credit Union Administration, the Federal Reserve Board, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and the Office of Thrift Supervision. About the FFIEC, http://www.ffiec.gov/ about.htm (last visited Oct. 16, 2009). Congress established the FFIEC in 1979 as an interagency body to prescribe uniform examination procedures, and to promote uniform supervision, among the federal agencies responsible for the examination and supervision of financial institutions. Id. In 1980, Congress gave the FFIEC responsibility for public access to HMDA data. See 2006 HMDA Data, supra note 88 at 73. 90 Rooting Out Discrimination Hearing, supra note 81, at 450 (response to questions submitted by Calvin R. Hagins). 91 Id. at 42. 92 The argument that the HMDA data do not prove discrimination cuts both ways. These data also do not exonerate lenders from discrimination. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 287 Despite the advantages of including credit history information in HMDA data, limitations will continue to exist because the credit score is only one of many risk assessment variables lenders use to price loans. It must therefore be remembered that adding credit scores to HMDA data analyses will not transform these data into something other than the screening tool Congress envisioned. Yet the additional information will make the screening tool sharper in that it will be able to do a better job of identifying potential discrimination. This enhancement to federal oversight of the subprime market is appropriate given the concern that discriminatory practices are part of the foundation of the mortgage foreclosure crisis. Still, other concerns must be considered. 1. Increased Lender Vulnerability to Litigation Credit score data would likely make some lenders vulnerable to fair lending lawsuits by individuals who believe that HMDA data, without more, conclusively identify discriminatory pricing. Even if lenders could successfully defend such lawsuits by providing additional credit risk or other explanations that sufficiently justify the pricing disparities, the expense of defending unsubstantiated claims can be costly.93 Additionally, the reputational harm that could result from accusations of racial discrimination may be difficult to repair. Another negative consequence for subprime lenders would be the cost of adjusting their systems for the reporting of the additional HMDA data. This cost is unknown and certainly must be considered, However, credit score data would reduce the possibility that racial disparities reflect discriminatory treatment. Also, some legal scholars question whether credit scores are racially biased. See Chi Chi Wu, Credit Scoring and Insurance: Costing Consumers Billions and Perpetuating the Economic Racial Divide. 1–18 (2007), available at http://www.consumerlaw.org/reports/ content/InsuranceScoring.pdf. 93 Engel & McCoy, supra note 84. Kathleen Engel & Patricia McCoy discussed the reporting of credit score information with a representative from the lending industry who implied that exposure to frivolous lawsuits was a downside to collection of these data. Id. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 288 however, given the need for greater insight into the lending practices in the subprime market, this cost should not justify keeping credit score data from fair lending regulators at the time they receive the HMDA data.94 2. Consumer Privacy Consumer privacy concerns are sometimes cited as a justification for omitting credit score information from HMDA data reporting requirements.95 Unfortunately, HMDA data can now be matched with other information (e.g., public records of property transfers) to determine the identity of individual borrowers. Adding credit score information to the HMDA data requirements could further compromise the privacy of borrowers because once the matching is done and the borrowers are identified, it would be possible to learn their credit scores. Obviously, consumers should not have to worry about their credit scores becoming publicly available because they applied for a mortgage loan. Given the validity of the privacy concern, it is difficult to argue that it is outweighed by the usefulness of the additional credit score data. This, however, should not end the discussion. Efforts should be made to address consumer privacy concerns in a manner that is consistent with requiring lenders to report credit score information. What is needed is a solution to the credit score reporting issue that does not compromise consumer privacy. According to two legal scholars, the United States Census Bureau has developed ways to protect privacy so that researchers can gain access to individual level census data without reporting a respondent’s identity.96 The FRB should examine these methods to see if they are suitable for safeguarding consumer privacy in the context of reporting credit 94 If credit score information is captured and analyzed with current HMDA data, banking regulators should be able to identify more expeditiously financial institutions with suspicious lending patterns. This approach may therefore reduce inefficiency in fair lending enforcement. 95 See Gramlich, supra note 79. 96 See supra note 84. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 289 score data. Another approach that is ripe for exploration is for subprime lenders to report the credit score information to the FRB for its internal use only. The FRB analysts would crunch the data and initiate investigations if racial disparities persisted after taking credit histories into account.97 By restricting the data disclosure to the FRB only, public disclosure is avoided and consumer privacy is maintained. Additionally, both the Census Bureau approach and the FRB internal use approach would avoid exposing lenders to frivolous lawsuits.98 The FRB should explore these or comparable privacy safeguards that would remove barriers to obtaining credit scores at the same time demographic and other HMDA data are obtained. Adding credit scores would promote greater transparency of the lending practices in the subprime mortgage market and in turn will likely increase ECOA compliance efforts of subprime lenders. The HMDA analyses that include credit scores will help explain to banking regulators whether any racial disparities are due to legitimate nondiscriminatory factors or to illegal discrimination.99 3. Access to Credit: The Government’s Role A credit score reporting requirement might cause some subprime lenders to curtail the availability of credit to higherrisk borrowers. The risk of bad public relations, litigation, and more regulatory scrutiny would undoubtedly influence these decisions. Yet racial minorities may be hurt if subprime lenders cut back on making loans, as would other ECOA group 100 members who are protected by the fair lending laws. To be 97 See id. See id. 99 See Rooting Out Discrimination Hearing, supra note 81, at 89 (prepared statement of Calvin R. Hagins). 100 Home Mortgage Disclosure Act: Newly Collected Data and What it Means: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit of H. Comm. on Financial Servs., 109th Cong. 138 (2006) (prepared statement of Professor Michael E. Staten, Director, Credit Research Center, McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University) 98 TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 290 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY sure, subprime lending is an important element of our financial system because it provides a way for many people with blemished credit records, minority and non-minority, to become homeowners or obtain home financing who may otherwise be unable to do so.101 Given their defective credit histories, and perhaps other vulnerabilities, subprime borrowers have few financial options available and thus are more susceptible to predatory lending practices.102 Paradoxically, the question becomes whether the “access to credit” concern outweighs the benefit of having HMDA data that can more accurately identify possible ECOA violators. As discussed in Part I above, the legacy of redlining discrimination where traditional lenders have failed to serve minority communities is a contributing factor to the problem of predatory subprime lending and discrimination in these communities.103 Denying loans to minority borrowers at reasonable and fair rates creates voids that can be quickly filled by predatory lenders that charge exorbitant mortgage rates and fees. In essence, a large part of the problem for minority borrowers who turn to predatory subprime lenders is that in many minority neighborhoods there is very little, if any, competition for mortgage loans.104 These lenders sometimes use [hereinafter HMDA New Data Hearing]. Professor Staten voices the concerns of Federal Reserve Board Governor Susan Schmidt Bies about reducing mortgage credit availability for higher-risk borrowers in his testimony on the misuse of the HMDA pricing data. Id. 101 See Mayer & Pence, supra note 6, at 3 (finding that subprime loans appear to provide credit in locations where credit might be more difficult to obtain); see also Christopher R. Childs, Comment, So You’ve Been Preempted—What Are You Going To Do Now?: Solutions for States Following Federal Preemption of State Predatory Lending Statutes, 2004 BYU L. REV. 701, 709 (discussing what is predatory lending and why it is harmful). 102 See Warren, supra note 17 (discussing the effects of predatory lending). 103 See supra Part I. 104 See Problems in Community Development, Banking, Mortgage Lending Discrimination, Reverse Redlining, and Home Equity Lending: Hearings Before the S. Comm. on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 291 abusive and discriminatory lending practices. But not all subprime lending is predatory or discriminatory, which means that all subprime borrowers are not victims.105 As Federal Reserve Governor Susan Schmidt Bies admonished, if expanded HMDA data requirements lead to the “unwarranted tarnishing of a lender’s reputation, this could reduce the willingness of that lender or another to remain in, or enter, certain higher-priced segments of the market.”106 Indeed, the possibility of cutting off some legitimate subprime mortgage credit sources of people with already limited credit options is something that must be carefully considered before expanding HMDA to include credit scores. On the other hand, adding credit score information to the HMDA reporting requirement of subprime lenders could help federal regulators better identify subprime lenders who use racially discriminatory lending practices. One way out of this conundrum is for the federal government to provide subprime borrowers with additional mortgage credit sources. This approach addresses the diminished credit problem and consequently removes this obstacle to allowing regulators to obtain credit score data that could better assist them in overseeing the subprime mortgage market. Along these lines, Professor Ronald Silverman has proposed an attractive idea that merits serious consideration. He suggests that Congress tackle the predatory lending problem by providing funding to credit unions for the purpose of making additional subprime mortgage loans.107 This proposal has several 103d Cong. 392 (1993) (written testimony of John B. Long and Thomas W. Tucker, Partners, Dye, Tucker, Everitt, Wheale & Long; and David E. Hudson, Partner, Hull, Towill, Norman & Barrett). 105 The terms “subprime” and “predatory” lending are frequently and erroneously used interchangeably to refer to abusive and unscrupulous lending practices. While subprime loans certainly pose inherent financial risks, and lenders are susceptible to engaging in predatory practices, subprime loans are not inherently abusive or predatory but serve an appropriate function in the market. See Andre K. Gray, Comment, Caveat Emptor: Let the Borrower Beware of the Subprime Mortgage Market, 11 U. PA. J.L. & SOC. CHANGE 195, 195 (2008). 106 See HMDA New Data Hearing, supra note 100, at 138. 107 Silverman, supra note 18, at 585–87. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 292 advantages. First, it would provide competition to predatory subprime lenders, including those who use discriminatory lending practices. As a result, subprime minority borrowers will have alternative means of obtaining mortgage credit through legitimate sources. This would help to eliminate racial discrimination in the subprime market. Second, credit unions are regulated at the state or federal level and are subject to the ECOA’s anti-discrimination mandate. Consequently, the subprime lending that credit unions provide is already, and will continue to be, examined for fair lending compliance. Third, as non-profit depository institutions with a long history of providing financial services to people of modest means, credit unions are likely to imbue public trust.108 Finally, as Professor Silverman so aptly notes, “a supportive government presence need not involve the federal government as the lender of either first or last resort.”109 Thus, the federal government would not become a mortgage bank under the credit union funding approach. Congress should fully examine the idea of a government supported subprime mortgage loan alternative to predatory lenders. Buying a home is the most expensive purchase most consumers will ever make. Because of the substantial investment borrowers make when purchasing or refinancing a home, it is imperative that they enter mortgage transactions in an environment of trust and honesty. By providing funding to credit unions, Congress can assist minority borrowers in avoiding lenders that use abusive and racially discriminatory practices. At the same time, the FRB could move forward with requiring subprime lenders to report credit score data without jeopardizing home mortgage credit for subprime borrowers. CONCLUSION Predatory lenders are destroying the reputation of legitimate subprime lenders who provide valuable mortgage services to 108 109 See id. at 582–585. Id. at 586. TAYLOR REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:35 PM ELIMINATING RACIAL DISCRIMINATION 293 various segments of the population that would otherwise be unable to afford or refinance a home. These predators bring to subprime lending not only abusive tactics but discriminatory practices as well—a combination that can wreak havoc on people and communities of color. As we continue to seek solutions to predatory lending, we should not forget the role that racial discrimination plays in the abusive subprime market. This persistent problem must be addressed if solutions for stopping the next subprime crisis are to be effective. Part of the solution at the federal level is to bolster enforcement of consumer protection laws. Accordingly, government attorneys should bring more enforcement actions against subprime lenders that engage in discrimination in violation of the ECOA. Additionally, the FRB should facilitate these litigation efforts by providing ECOA enforcement authorities with a better means of identifying predatory lenders that discriminate unlawfully. Requiring subprime lenders to report credit score data would be an invaluable tool in uncovering discriminatory conduct. Moreover, Congress can help solve this problem by changing the environment in which predatory lenders thrive, namely, in places where borrowers have few mortgage lending alternatives to unscrupulous home loan providers. By funding credit unions, the federal government can facilitate competition in the subprime market and thus provide viable mortgage funding options to vulnerable consumers. While growing calls for stopping predatory subprime mortgage lending are positive steps in the right direction, effective solutions must include holding subprime lenders liable and accountable for lending discrimination on the basis of race and other illegal factors. ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO THE EXPANDING TERRY STOP Daniel C. Isaacs* INTRODUCTION 1 In Miranda v. Arizona, the Supreme Court interpreted the Fifth Amendment privilege against self-incrimination by holding that police may not interrogate a person taken into custody without first reading to the suspect their now-familiar Miranda rights.2 The question of what constitutes “police custody” is particularly vexing in the context of “Terry stops:” warrantless searches and seizures based upon reasonable suspicion, limited in scope, to determine whether a person is armed or in the midst of criminal activity.3 As the lawful scope of a Terry stop has expanded beyond its narrow and limited genesis in Terry v. Ohio,4 federal circuits have been unable to reach a consensus regarding whether a lawful Terry stop may constitute Miranda custody.5 The First and Fourth Circuits hold that a suspect is not in Miranda custody if the Terry stop was lawful, i.e. reasonable.6 Conversely, the Second, Seventh, Eighth, Ninth, and Tenth Circuits hold that the reasonableness of a Terry stop is irrelevant as to Miranda custody; if the circumstances of a * J.D. Candidate, Brooklyn Law School, 2010; B.A., Binghamton University, 2007. Special thanks to my parents and Laura for their encouragement, the entire staff of the Journal of Law and Policy for their endless editing assistance, and my friends for listening. 1 Miranda v. Arizona, 384 U.S. 436 (1966). 2 Id. at 444. 3 Terry v. Ohio, 392 U.S. 1, 27–31 (1968). 4 See infra Part I(B). 5 E.g., United States v. Newton, 369 F.3d 659, 673 (2d Cir. 2004). 6 E.g., United States v. Leshuk, 65 F.3d 1105, 1110 (4th Cir. 1995). 383 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 384 Terry stop meet the threshold of Miranda custody, then Miranda warnings are required before the suspect of a Terry stop may be interrogated.7 This note argues that the determination of whether a suspect is in “Miranda custody” does not turn on the legality of the Terry stop. Part I will review Terry v. Ohio and present the dramatic expansion of the scope of a Terry stop.8 Part II will review Miranda v. Arizona and explain how courts have neglected to clarify the definition of Miranda custody.9 Part III will survey the circuit split regarding Miranda’s application to a Terry stop.10 Part IV will argue for the Second Circuit’s independent approach, and finally Part V will evaluate documented criticisms of this proposal.11 I. TERRY V. OHIO A. “Stop and Frisks:” An Exception to Probable Cause Under the Fourth Amendment,12 warrantless searches and seizures are presumed unreasonable.13 However, the Supreme Court has created several exceptions to the presumptive warrant requirement.14 The Warren Court sanctioned one such exception in Terry v. 7 Newton, 369 F.3d at 673. See infra Part I. 9 See infra Part II. 10 See infra Part III. 11 See infra Part IV; Part V. 12 U.S. CONST. amend. IV (“The right of the people to be secure . . . against unreasonable searches and seizures, shall not be violated, and no Warrants shall issue, but upon probable cause . . . .”). 13 Katz v. United States, 389 U.S. 347, 357 (1967). 14 See, e.g., Brigham City v. Stuart, 547 U.S. 398, 403 (2006) (permitting a warrantless entry of a home when police have an objectively reasonable basis for believing that a person within the home is seriously injured or threatened with injury); United States v. Watson, 423 U.S. 411, 414 (1976) (permitting a public arrest in the absence of a warrant); Warden v. Hayden, 387 U.S. 294, 310 (1967) (permitting a warrantless search that is justified when officers are in “hot pursuit”). 8 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 385 Ohio.15 “Where a police officer observes . . . conduct which leads him reasonably to conclude . . . that criminal activity may be afoot and that the persons with whom he is dealing may be armed and presently dangerous . . . he is entitled for the protection of himself and others . . . to conduct” a search reasonably related in scope to the initial justification for the search.16 In Terry, a police officer observed two pedestrians, Terry and Chilton, conducting “elaborately casual and oftrepeated reconnaissance” in front of a store window.17 The officer approached the two pedestrians, along with a third man with whom they were meeting, identified himself as a police officer, patted down the outside of Terry’s clothing, and found a 18 .38-caliber revolver. He discovered another revolver in Chilton’s overcoat pocket.19 After disarming the men, Chilton and Terry were formally charged with carrying concealed weapons.20 The issue presented to the Warren Court was whether “in all the circumstances of this on-the-street encounter, [Terry’s] right to personal security was violated by an unreasonable search and seizure.”21 The Court analyzed the reasonableness of the search by balancing the government’s interest in law enforcement and public safety with the “nature and quality of the intrusion on individual rights.”22 First, the Court “emphatically”23 rejected the notion that a 24 “stop and frisk” did not implicate the Fourth Amendment. 15 Terry v. Ohio, 392 U.S. 1, 30 (1968). Id. at 30. 17 Id. at 6. 18 Id. at 7. 19 Id. 20 Id. 21 Id. at 9. 22 Id. at 24. 23 Id. at 16. 24 Id. It must be recognized that whenever a police officer accosts an individual and restrains his freedom to walk away, he has “seized” that person. And it is nothing less than sheer torture of the English 16 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 386 Second, the Court considered the societal importance of permitting police officers to investigate their suspicions of criminal or dangerous activity with less than probable cause.25 Chief Justice Warren noted that while law enforcement has an interest in effective crime prevention and detection,26 there is an additional, more “immediate interest” concerning a police officer’s safety and assurance that he is not dealing with an armed individual.27 Thus, the Court agreed that police officers must be afforded an effective tool to protect themselves and the public in situations where they may lack probable cause for a search or arrest.28 Finally, the Court balanced the needs of law enforcement and public safety against the intrusion of privacy.29 Chief Justice Warren acknowledged that “even a limited search of the outer clothing for weapons constitutes a severe, though brief, intrusion upon cherished personal security, and it must surely be an annoying, frightening, and perhaps humiliating experience.”30 Regardless, the proper compromise between the competing interests of law enforcement and civil rights permitted a narrow exception to the Fourth Amendment’s probable cause requirement.31 The Court stressed that “[t]he sole justification” of a Terry stop is the “protection of the police officer and others nearby . . . .”32 language to suggest that a careful exploration of the outer surfaces of a person’s clothing all over his or her body in an attempt to find weapons is not a “search.” Moreover, it is simply fantastic to urge that such a procedure performed in public by a policeman while the citizen stands helpless . . . is a petty indignity. Id. 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 Id. Id. Id. Id. Id. Id. Id. Id. at 22. at 23. at 24. at 29. ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 387 B. The Expansion of Terry The permissible degree of intrusion during a “stop and frisk” has significantly expanded since 1968.33 In Terry, the Court permitted a “carefully limited search of the outer clothing . . . in an attempt to discover weapons which might be used to assault [the police officer].”34 Early cases following Terry interpreted this rule narrowly, hesitant to stray too far from this limited exception to the probable cause requirement.35 In United States v. Strickler, for example, because police officers encircled the defendant in his car with their weapons raised,36 the Ninth Circuit found it impossible to “equate [this] armed approach to a surrounded vehicle whose occupants have been commanded to raise their hands with the ‘brief stop of a suspicious individual in order to determine his identity or to maintain the status quo momentarily while obtaining more information’ . . . .”37 Accordingly, the Terry stop was unreasonable.38 In United States v. McLemure, the Tenth Circuit rejected the government’s argument that an officer acted reasonably when he drew his weapon, forced the defendant to lie face down, and 39 conducted a pat down. Construing Terry narrowly, the court 33 See United States v. Chaidez, 919 F.2d 1193, 1198 (7th Cir. 1990). Terry, 392 U.S. at 30. 35 See United States v. O’Looney, 544 F.2d 385, 390 (9th Cir. 1976) (finding a Terry stop valid, in part because of the absence of drawn weapons, handcuffs, force, and threats thereof); see also United States v. McLemure, 573 F.2d 1154 (10th Cir. 1978); United States v. Strickler, 490 F.2d 378 (9th Cir. 1974). 36 Strickler, 490 F.2d 378–79. The Ninth Circuit concluded that “[t]he restriction of Strickler’s ‘liberty of movement’ was complete when he was encircled by police and confronted with official orders made at gunpoint . . . [n]o significant, new restraint was added when Officer Ripley, a few moments later, handcuffed Strickler and formally pronounced him ‘under arrest.’” Id. at 380 (internal citations omitted). 37 Id. 38 Id. 39 United States v. McLemure, 573 F.2d 1154, 1156 (10th Cir. 1978). 34 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 388 concluded the Terry stop was unreasonable.40 Similarly, the defendant in Dunaway v. New York 41 was transported against his will to the local police station and held in an interrogation room where he was not free to leave.42 The Court held the police conduct exceeded the brief detention authorized by Terry because “in contrast to the brief and narrowly circumscribed intrusions involved in those cases, the detention of petitioner was in important respects indistinguishable from a traditional arrest.”43 More recently, however, the permissible degree of intrusion permitted during a Terry stop has expanded far beyond the “stop and frisk” originally upheld by the Supreme Court,44 presumably 45 as courts responded to rising violent crime. In Florida v. 46 Royer, the Court acknowledged, “the predicate permitting seizures on suspicion short of probable cause is that law enforcement interests warrant a limited intrusion on the personal security of the suspect,”47 but opened the door to Terry’s expansion by explaining in dicta that “the scope of the intrusion will vary” with the circumstances of each case.48 In United 40 Id. Dunaway v. New York, 442 U.S. 200 (1979). 42 Id. at 202–03. 43 Id. 44 The cases discussed in this section are not intended to be exhaustive, but merely describe the willingness of courts to permit increasingly coercive police conduct during Terry stops. 45 “The number of police officers killed annually in the line of duty has tripled since Terry was decided; the number of those assaulted and wounded has risen by a factor of twenty.” United States v. Micheletti, 13 F.3d 838, 844 (5th Cir. 1994). 46 Florida v. Royer, 460 U.S. 491 (1983). In Royer, the defendant purchased an airline ticket under an assumed name. He was questioned by police officers and his suitcases were searched. Royer moved to suppress the evidence obtained by the search of his suitcases. The Court ultimately determined that the detainment and search of Royer exceeded the legal scope of an investigative stop, and the evidence was suppressed. Id. at 493–501. 47 Id. at 500. 48 Id. 41 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 389 States v. Perdue,49 police officers approached the defendant’s car with their weapons drawn and ordered the defendant to step out and lie facedown on the ground.50 Then, the police allegedly handcuffed the defendant and questioned him.51 The Tenth Circuit concluded that while the officers’ warrantless seizure of Perdue “border[ed] on an illegal arrest,” it was nonetheless a reasonable Terry stop because the intrusion was justified by the potentially dangerous circumstances of the encounter.52 In United States v. Quinn,53 police parked their cars behind the defendant’s vehicle, blocked his exit, and questioned him for twenty minutes until more officers arrived with drug-sniffing dogs.54 The court concluded that the Terry stop was lawful and saw “no way that the agents could have greatly shortened their inquiry if they were to ‘confirm or dispel their suspicions’ meaningfully.”55 Additionally, the Quinn court observed the emerging patchwork of law regarding the lawfulness of Terry stops: 49 United States v. Perdue, 8 F.3d 1455 (10th Cir. 1993). Id. at 1458–59. 51 Id. 52 Id. at 1462 (“It was not unreasonable under the circumstances for the officers to execute the Terry stop with their weapons drawn. While Terry stops generally must be fairly nonintrusive [sic], officers may take necessary steps to protect themselves if the circumstances reasonably warrant such measures. ‘[T]he use of guns in connection with a stop is permissible where the police reasonably believe [the weapons] are necessary for their protection.’ United States v. Merritt, 695 F.2d 1263, 1273 (10th Cir. 1982). Similarly, other circuits have held that police officers may draw their weapons without transforming an otherwise valid Terry stop into an arrest. See, e.g., United States v. Alvarez, 899 F.2d 833, 838 (9th Cir. 1990); United States v. Taylor, 857 F.2d 210, 214 (4th Cir. 1988); United States v. Serna-Barreto, 842 F.2d 965, 968 (7th Cir. 1988); United States v. Jones, 759 F.2d 633, 638 (8th Cir. 1985); United States v. Jackson, 652 F.2d 244, 249 (2d Cir. 1981).”) (internal citations omitted). “The Fourth Amendment does not require that officers unnecessarily risk their lives when encountering a suspect whom they reasonably believe to be armed and dangerous.” Id. at 1463. 53 United States v. Quinn, 815 F.2d 153 (1st Cir. 1987). 54 Id. at 155–56. 55 Id. at 158. 50 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 390 [a]dmittedly, Terry, Dunaway, Royer, and Place,56 considered together, may in some instances create difficult line-drawing problems in distinguishing an investigative stop from a de facto arrest . . . . But our cases impose no rigid time limitation on Terry stops. While it is clear that “the brevity of the invasion of the individual’s Fourth Amendment interests is an important factor in determining whether the seizure is so minimally intrusive as to be justifiable on reasonable suspicion,” . . . we have emphasized the need to consider the law enforcement purposes to be served by the stop as well as the time reasonably needed to effectuate those purposes.57 Thus, Quinn acknowledged the increasing deference given to law enforcement in their administration of a Terry stop. A year later, in United States v. Serna-Barreto, Judge Posner, writing for the Seventh Circuit, deemed a Terry stop valid when the investigating officer “pointed his gun at . . . [the defendant] . . . [and] ordered her out of the car.”58 The court upheld the stop, in large part because “many drug traffickers are armed and they sometimes shoot policemen”59 and because the defendant “testified that she was not scared by the gun.”60 Similarly, in United States v. Greene61 and United States v. 62 Hardnett, the Ninth and Sixth Circuits, respectively, deemed a 56 United States v. Place, 462 U.S. 696 (1983). Quinn, 815 F.2d at 159 (footnotes citing cases mentioned therein added). 58 United States v. Serna-Barreto, 842 F.2d 965, 967 (7th Cir. 1988). 59 Id. at 967. 60 Id. at 968. Although subjective belief is not determinative on whether an ostensible stop is actually an arrest, Serna-Barreto’s testimony is strong evidence in an otherwise sketchy record that, if Officer Dailey did in fact point his gun at her, he did so in a manner that protected him without unduly threatening her. Id. 61 United States v. Greene, 783 F.2d 1364 (9th Cir. 1986). 62 United States v. Hardnett, 804 F.2d 353 (6th Cir. 1986). 57 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 391 warrantless investigative stop valid under Terry even though the officer’s weapons were drawn.63 The Seventh Circuit’s reasoning in United States v. Tilmon64 best illustrates the scope of the expansion of Terry.65 In Tilmon, police were looking for a suspected bank robber.66 A police officer spotted the vehicle described in the radio dispatch and called for back-up units; he noted the driver “‘slid down in the drivers seat’ as the police car approached . . . .”67 Next, the police cars activated their flashing lights and Tilmon pulled over. Over a loud speaker, Tilmon was informed . . . that he should get out of the car with his hands up and lie face down on the shoulder of the road. Tilmon immediately complied. (According to Officer Klanderman, some of the weapons were pointed at Tilmon, and some were pointed at his car.) After he lay down as directed, Tilmon was handcuffed and placed in a squad car. A shotgun was pointed at Tilmon’s head while he was handcuffed, searched and seated in the squad car . . . . At the scene of the highway stop, Tilmon’s car had been effectively blocked. There were at least five squad cars abreast of and behind his car, and another police car stopped one-quarter mile ahead of Tilmon’s car on the shoulder of the road . . . . Officer Klanderman testified that drawing weapons was standard procedure for a felony stop “for the safety of the officers and any other persons that may be in the area.”68 In rejecting Tilmon’s argument that the warrantless stop was so forceful as to constitute a de facto arrest, and thus a violation 63 See Greene, 783 F.2d at 1367; Hardnett, 804 F.2d at 357. United States v. Tilmon, 19 F.3d 1221 (7th Cir. 1993). 65 Id. Tilmon has been cited as recently as April 11, 2008, specifically for its proposition that if found to be justified, requiring a suspect to lie face down while being handcuffed and/or briefly detained in an officer’s squad car does not convert a Terry stop into an arrest. Jewett v. Anders, 521 F.3d 818, 825–26 (7th Cir. 2008). 66 Tilmon, 19 F.3d at 1223. 67 Id. 68 Id. 64 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 392 of the Fourth Amendment, the court recited the elements of a valid Terry stop: [t]he reasonableness of an investigatory stop may be determined by examining: (1) whether the police were aware of specific and articulable facts giving rise to reasonable suspicion; and (2) whether the degree of intrusion was reasonably related to the known facts. In other words, the issue is whether the police conduct— given their suspicions and the surrounding circumstances—was reasonable.69 The court concluded that the “police justifiably held a reasonable suspicion that the car and its driver were involved in a bank robbery.”70 Moreover, it found that based on the circumstances of this particular matter—specifically that the suspect was thought to be an armed felon—the scope of the intrusion was reasonable.71 The court emphasized the risks posed to law 72 enforcement, particularly in a “felony stop:” [w]hen effecting a Terry stop . . . police officers must make a quick decision about how to protect themselves and others from possible danger. They are not necessarily required to “adopt alternative means to ensure their safety in order to avoid the intrusion involved in a Terry encounter.” A court in its assessment “should take care to consider whether the police are acting in a swiftly developing situation, and in such cases the court should not indulge in unrealistic second-guessing.”73 Thus, “[t]o require an officer to risk his life in order to make an investigatory stop would run contrary to the intent of Terry v. Ohio.”74 Finally, the Tilmon court took notice of Terry’s expansion: 69 Id. at 1224 (citing Terry v. Ohio, 392 U.S. 1, 19–20 (1968)). Id. at 1225. 71 Id. at 1227. 72 Id. at 1225–26. 73 Id. at 1225 (citations omitted). 74 Id. at 1226 (citing United States v. Maslanka, 501 F.2d 208, 213 n.10 (5th Cir. 1974)). 70 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 393 [i]n the recent past, the “permissible reasons for a stop and search and the permissible scope of the intrusion [under the Terry doctrine] have expanded beyond their original contours.” The last decade “has witnessed a multifaceted expansion of Terry,” including the “trend granting officers greater latitude in using force in order to ‘neutralize’ potentially dangerous suspects during an investigatory detention.” For better or for worse, the trend has led to the permitting of the use of handcuffs, the placing of suspects in police cruisers, the drawing of weapons and other measures of force more traditionally associated with arrest than with investigatory detention.75 The court’s language makes clear that the justifications for the stark departure from Terry’s narrow holding are the same as the policy considerations that encouraged its advancement in the first place. The increase in violent crime, gun violence, America’s war on illegal drugs, and criminal sophistication since 1968 has enhanced the dangers associated with law enforcement.76 Once the Supreme Court permitted an exception to the probable cause requirement, lower courts that evaluated the legality of officers’ actions on a case-by-case basis felt compelled to maximize the tools officers had to protect their safety.77 75 Id. at 1224–25 (citations omitted) (emphasis added). “The number of police officers killed annually in the line of duty has tripled since Terry was decided; the numbers of those assaulted and wounded have risen by a factor of twenty.” United States v. Michelletti, 13 F.3d 838, 844 (5th Cir. 1994). 77 In sum, in 1963, Officer McFadden stopped a person he reasonably believed to be preparing for a robbery and frisked his outer clothing for the presence of a weapon that could serve to harm the police officer or the public. Terry v. Ohio, 392 U.S. 1, 7, 23, 28 (1968). In 1992, Spencer Ray Tilmon was surrounded by five police cars and numerous police officers whose arms were drawn, laid down on the ground on an interstate highway, handcuffed while a shotgun was pointed at his head, and placed in a squad car during the search of his car. United States v. Tilmon, 19 F.3d 1221, 1223 (7th Cir. 1994). Both courts found the officers had the requisite specific and articulable facts to support reasonable suspicion of the defendants’ propensity for crime or imposition of public danger, and both courts 76 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 394 II. MIRANDA V. ARIZONA: PROTECTING THE PRIVILEGE AGAINST SELF-INCRIMINATION A. Miranda v. Arizona Two years before Terry, the Warren Court addressed the Fifth Amendment privilege against self-incrimination78 in Miranda v. Arizona.79 In the consolidated cases decided in Miranda, police questioned a suspect in custody at the precinct for an extended period of time, eventually eliciting a confession.80 The Court set out to decide the trial admissibility of statements obtained from questioning which shared certain “salient features [including] incommunicado interrogation of individuals in a police-dominated atmosphere [that] result[ed] in self-incriminating statements without full warnings of constitutional rights.”81 The Warren Court sought to ensure that suspects’ Fifth Amendment privilege against self-incrimination was adequately protected during the course of custodial interrogation.82 Miranda responded to the coercive nature that a police-dominated environment has on the will of a suspect in custody;83 that is, when police conduct psychologically coercive in-custody interrogation techniques, procedural safeguards must be employed to offset their effect. First, the Court reiterated that the Fifth Amendment privilege is available “outside of criminal court proceedings and serves to protect persons in all settings in which their freedom of action is curtailed in any significant way concluded that the intrusiveness of the subsequent search was reasonable under the circumstances and sufficiently limited in scope. See Terry, 392 U.S. at 30; Tilmon, 19 F.3d at 1225, 1228. 78 U.S. CONST. amend. V (“No person shall be compelled in any criminal case to be a witness against himself . . . .”). 79 Miranda v. Arizona, 384 U.S. 436, 439 (1966). 80 Id. at 440. 81 Id. at 445. 82 Id. at 439. 83 See id. at 443. ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 395 from being compelled to incriminate themselves.”84 Second, the court emphasized that “an understanding of the nature and setting of this in-custody interrogation is essential” to the Court’s holding.85 In light of the one-sided nature of police interrogation and the value of the privilege against selfincrimination,86 the Court held that the “prosecution may not use statements, stemming from custodial interrogation of the defendant unless it demonstrates the use of procedural safeguards effective to secure the privilege against selfincrimination.”87 These required procedural safeguards must inform the defendant that “he has the right to remain silent, that any statement he does make may be used as evidence against him, and that he has the right to the presence of an attorney.”88 Accordingly, Miranda warnings are required when the subject is (1) in police custody and (2) interrogated by the police.89 The Court defined custodial interrogation as “questioning initiated by law enforcement officers after a person has been taken into custody or otherwise deprived of his freedom of action in any 90 significant way.” Subsequent lower courts have struggled to identify the appropriate threshold of custody and interrogation that triggers Miranda. 1. Miranda Custody The Supreme Court specifically addressed whether an 84 Id. at 467. Id. at 445. The Court commented on the history of physically abusive interrogation tactics, but stressed that coercion can be mental as well as physical. See id. at 446, 449. In the Court’s own words, the compulsion directed towards suspects stems from the individual being “swept from familiar surroundings,” being “surrounded by antagonistic forces,” and being “subject to techniques intended to subjugate the individual to the will of his examiner.” Id. at 457, 461. 86 Id. at 468. 87 Id. at 444. 88 Id. 89 Id. 90 Id. The Court did not articulate with further specificity factors indicative of custodial interrogation. 85 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 396 arrestee was in sufficient custody as to warrant Miranda warnings in Orozco v. Texas.91 Justice Black rejected the state’s argument that since the suspect was in familiar surroundings (his bedroom), Miranda did not apply.92 Instead, the Court laid down a bright-line rule: if a person is arrested, he is in custody for purposes of Miranda.93 In California v. Beheler,94 the suspect agreed to accompany police officers to the police station for questioning.95 The suspect was informed he was not under arrest. He left, unrestrained, after the questioning.96 The Court stated: although the circumstances of each case must certainly influence a determination of whether a suspect is “in custody” for purposes of receiving of Miranda protection, the ultimate inquiry is simply whether there is a “formal arrest or restraint on freedom of movement” of the degree associated with a formal arrest . . . [b]ut we have explicitly recognized that Miranda warnings are not required “simply because the questioning takes place in the station house, or because the questioned person is one whom the police suspect.”97 Accordingly, the Court found that Beheler was not in custody for Miranda purposes, forcefully explaining, “it is beyond doubt that Beheler was neither taken into custody nor significantly deprived of his freedom of action. Indeed, 91 Orozco v. Texas, 394 U.S. 324 (1969). Id. at 326. 93 Id. at 326–27. Justice White’s dissent expressed disdain that the custody requirement of Miranda was “dilute[d].” Id. at 330. Relying on the language in Miranda that focused on the extremes and coerciveness of inhouse custodial interrogations, Justice White argued that Miranda and the policies underlying it were not meant to reach beyond the police station and criticized the majority for assuming, without discussion, that it did so. Id. at 329. 94 California v. Beheler, 463 U.S. 1121 (1983). 95 Id. at 1122. 96 Id. 97 Id. at 1125. 92 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 397 Beheler’s freedom was not restricted in any way whatsoever.”98 The Supreme Court’s next significant decision regarding Miranda custody came in Berkemer v. McCarty.99 In this case, an Ohio state highway patrolman stopped a suspect weaving in and out of a highway lane.100 At the scene of the traffic stop, the officer asked the suspect if he had been using intoxicants and the suspect replied that he had “consumed two beers and had smoked several joints of marijuana . . . .”101 The suspect was arrested and later sought to have those statements suppressed on the grounds that he was not first read his Miranda rights at the scene of the traffic stop before his arrest.102 The Court held that “roadside questioning of a motorist detained pursuant to a routine traffic stop” was not “custodial interrogation.”103 The Court acknowledged that a usual traffic stop is analogous to a Terry stop and the nature of these detentions (Terry stops) “explains the absence of any suggestion in our opinions that Terry stops are subject to the dictates of Miranda.”104 The Court concluded, “fidelity to the doctrine announced in Miranda105 requires that it be enforced strictly, but only in those types of situations in which the concerns that powered the decision are implicated.”106 107 In United States v. Brown, the Eighth Circuit suggested six indicia for determining whether a suspect is in custody for Miranda purposes: 98 Id. at 1123. Berkemer v. McCarty, 468 U.S. 420 (1984). 100 Id. at 423. 101 Id. 102 See id. at 424. 103 Id. at 435. Berkemer also established an objective test to determine whether a suspect was “subjected to treatment that renders him ‘in custody:’” the “relevant inquiry is how a reasonable man in the suspect’s position would have understood his situation.” Id. at 440, 442. 104 Id. at 440. 105 Id. at 437. Specifically, the Court was referring to the phrase “deprived of his freedom of action in a significant way.” Id. at 428. 106 Id. at 437. 107 United States v. Brown, 990 F.2d 397 (8th Cir. 1993). 99 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 398 (1) whether the suspect was informed at the time of questioning that the questioning was voluntary, that the suspect was free to leave or request the officers to do so, or that the suspect was not considered under arrest; (2) whether the suspect possessed unrestrained freedom of movement during questioning; (3) whether the suspect initiated contact with authorities or voluntarily acquiesced to official request to respond to questions; (4) whether strong arm tactics or deceptive stratagems were employed during questioning; (5) whether the atmosphere of the questioning was police dominated; and (6) whether the suspect was placed under arrest at the termination of the questioning.108 Even if a person is in custody, however, he or she must still be “interrogated” in order to trigger Miranda.109 2. Miranda Interrogation Miranda defined interrogation as “questioning initiated by law enforcement officers,”110 but the Court has maintained that investigatory tactics other than direct questioning can be “interrogation.” In Rhode Island v. Innis,111 the Court held that “the term ‘interrogation’ under Miranda refers not only to express questioning, but also to any words or actions on the part of the police (other than those normally attendant to arrest and custody) that the police should know are reasonably likely to elicit an incriminating response from the suspect.”112 108 Id. at 399. “The presence of the first three indicia tends to mitigate the existence of custody at the time of questioning” while the “presence of the last three indicia aggravate the existence of custody.” Id. 109 See Alston v. Redman, 34 F.3d 1237, 1244 (3d Cir. 1994). 110 Miranda v. Arizona, 384 U.S. 436, 444 (1966). 111 Rhode Island v. Innis, 446 U.S. 291 (1980). 112 Id. at 301. ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 399 III. THE CIRCUITS’ SPLIT OVER MIRANDA’S APPLICABILITY TO TERRY STOPS Terry’s expansion to permit increasingly coercive searches and seizures113 has caught up to Miranda. The First and Fourth Circuits reason that if the Terry stop is lawful under the Fourth Amendment, then the suspect is not in Miranda custody.114 Conversely, the Second, Seventh, Eighth, Ninth, and Tenth Circuits consider the Fourth and Fifth Amendment questions separately, holding that a Terry stop may be lawful under the Fourth Amendment, but may still rise to a degree of intrusion that constitutes Miranda custody.115 A. The First and Fourth Circuits’ Categorical Approach The First and Fourth Circuits extend the holding of Berkemer from traffic stops to all lawful Terry stops, holding that if a Terry stop based upon reasonable suspicion is lawful at inception and in scope, then the suspect is not in Miranda custody.116 In other words, they apply a categorical rule that only if a Terry stop rises to the level of a de facto arrest, and thus is no longer a lawful Terry stop, would Miranda warnings be required. In United States v. Trueber,117 for example, police officers garnered reasonable suspicion that Trueber was smuggling drugs.118 Officers spoke with Trueber for ten-to-fifteen minutes 113 See supra Part I(B). United States v. Trueber, 238 F.3d 79 (1st Cir. 2001); United States v. Leshuk, 65 F.3d 1105 (4th Cir. 1995). 115 In United States v. Artiles–Martin, Judge Hodges noted that “[t]he First [and] Fourth . . . Circuits hold that so-called Terry reasonableness means Miranda warnings are not required, even if the stop was coercive . . . [while] the Second, Seventh, Ninth and Tenth Circuits hold that a coercive Terry stop requires warnings but still is deemed a valid Terry stop.” United States v. Artiles–Martin, No. 5:08-cr-14-Oc-10GRJ, 2008 WL 2600787, *11 n.38 (M.D. Fla. June 30, 2008). 116 Trueber, 238 F.3d 79; Leshuk, 65 F.3d 1105. 117 Trueber, 238 F.3d 79. 118 Id. at 82. 114 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 400 after pulling his truck over, and then for approximately one hour and twenty minutes further at his motel room.119 Agents kept Trueber under constant surveillance.120 Trueber was then arrested.121 The lower court suppressed all statements made by Trueber before his arrest, reasoning that “for purposes of Miranda, Trueber was in custody when questioned and, therefore, all statements violated Miranda and should be suppressed.”122 On appeal, the First Circuit concurred with Berkemer that “routine traffic stops are more analogous to a Terry stop than to a formal arrest, and, therefore, are not custodial for purposes of Miranda.”123 The court concluded that “the investigatory stop was justified at its inception and reasonably related in scope to the circumstances which justified the interference in the first place . . . [w]hat occurred was thus a permissible Terry stop.”124 Since “[n]othing the agents did or said sufficed to convert the investigatory stop into an arrest requiring the administration of Miranda warnings,” the statements’ suppression was 125 overturned. Trueber’s focus, on whether the stop was lawful or whether it exceeded the scope of a Terry stop to become a de facto arrest thus requiring Miranda warnings,126 suggests that only upon the latter circumstance, and never upon the former, would Miranda warnings be required.127 The Fourth Circuit also applies a categorical rule with regard to Miranda’s applicability to Terry stops. In United States v. 119 Id. at 84–85. Id. 121 Id. at 87. 122 Id. at 91. 123 Id. at 92 (citing Berkemer v. McCarty, 468 U.S. 420, 440 (1984)). 124 Id. at 95 (internal quotation marks and citation omitted). 125 Id. 126 Id. 127 A lower court in the First Circuit appears to have deviated from Trueber’s holding. In United States v. Massaro, the district court asserted that the First Circuit would recognize that “even during a lawful Terry stop, the restraint of a suspect can amount to a formal arrest.” United States v. Massaro, 560 F. Supp. 2d 96, 105 (D. Mass. 2008). 120 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 401 Leshuk,128 a turkey hunter uncovered marijuana growing in the woods.129 He alerted the police, and deputy sheriffs found the two defendants nearby with two backpacks and a brown plastic garbage bag in their possession.130 The deputies ordered the defendants to raise their hands, frisked them, and “determined they were not armed.”131 The deputies then asked several questions that the defendants answered.132 On appeal, Leshuk argued that his statements made during the deputies’ questioning at the scene, before his arrest, “should be suppressed because the deputies improperly interrogated him without administering warnings pursuant to Miranda.”133 The Leshuk court found that the officers’ conduct did not exceed the scope of a lawful Terry stop.134 The court distinguished a Terry stop from a custodial interrogation by noting that a Terry stop “must last no longer than necessary to verify or dispel the officer’s suspicion.”135 In sum, the First and Fourth Circuits have adopted a categorical rule that extends Berkemer’s holding: if the Terry stop was lawful, then the suspect was not in Miranda custody. However, not all circuits agree with this approach. B. The Second, Seventh, Eighth, Ninth, and Tenth Circuits’ Independent Approach These circuits reason that because a lawful Terry stop may include behavior commensurate with a formal arrest, a detainee of a lawful Terry stop, that is, a stop that does not rise to the level of a de facto arrest, may still be entitled to Miranda warnings. 128 129 130 131 132 133 134 135 United States v. Leshuk, 65 F.3d 1105 (4th Cir. 1995). Id. at 1106–07. Id. Id. at 1107. Id. Id. at 1108. Id. at 1110. Id. at 1109. ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 402 1. Second Circuit In United States v. Newton,136 three parole officers and three police officers arrived at the Wrights’ apartment upon word that the Wrights’ son, Newton, had threatened to kill the Wrights.137 The officers handcuffed Newton without advising him of his Miranda rights, explaining that it was for his and the officers’ safety, and that he was not under arrest.138 Newton thereafter told the police that he had a gun in his apartment and where it was.139 On appeal to the Second Circuit, Newton asserted that his responses to inquiries from the officers ought to have been suppressed because his restraint rose to a degree consistent with that of formal custody but was not preceded by Miranda warnings.140 The court rejected the categorical approach of the First and Fourth Circuit—that “where an investigatory stop is reasonable under the Fourth Amendment, the seized suspect is not ‘in custody’ for purposes of Miranda.”141 Rather, the Second Circuit found that Fourth Amendment reasonableness is not the standard for resolving Miranda custody challenges.142 In other words, “whether a ‘stop’ was permissible under Terry v. Ohio . . . is irrelevant to the Miranda analysis. Terry is an ‘exception’ to the Fourth Amendment probable cause requirement, not to the Fifth Amendment protections against self-incrimination.”143 Instead, the Second Circuit asked whether a “reasonable person in defendant’s position would have understood himself to be subjected to the restraints comparable to those associated with a 144 formal arrest.” Facts the court deemed relevant included: (1) the length of time involved in the stop; (2) its public 136 137 138 139 140 141 142 143 144 United States v. Newton, 369 F.3d 659 (2d Cir. 2004). Id. at 663. Id. Id. at 663–64. Id. at 668. Id. at 673 (citing Trueber and Leshuk). Id. Id. Id. (citing United States v. Ali, 69 F.3d 1467, 1472 (2d Cir. 1995)). ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 403 or private setting; (3) the number of participating law enforcement officers; (4) the risk of danger presented by the person stopped; and (5) the display or use of physical force against the person stopped, including firearms, handcuffs, and leg irons.145 The court’s willingness to extend Miranda protections to lawful Terry stops did not invalidate the lawfulness of the Terry stop: “the Fourth Amendment permits the officer to take ‘necessary measures . . . to neutralize the threat’ without converting a reasonable stop into a de facto arrest.”146 Accordingly, the Terry stop was reasonable under the Fourth Amendment, but “nevertheless placed him in custody for purposes of Miranda.”147 2. Seventh Circuit United States v. Smith148 considered whether a suspect detained and handcuffed during a Terry stop should have been read Miranda warnings.149 The court explained, “[t]he purpose of permitting a temporary detention without probable cause or a warrant is to protect police officers and the general public . . . [but] [t]he purpose of the Miranda rule, however, is 145 Id. at 674. Id. This is consistent with the Second Circuit’s decision in United States v. Ali, 68 F.3d 1468, 1473 (2d Cir. 1995): Terry is an “exception” to the Fourth Amendment probable cause requirement, not to the Fifth Amendment protections against selfincrimination . . . . The fact that the seizure and search of a suspect comports with the Fourth Amendment under Terry simply does not determine whether the suspect’s contemporaneous oral admissions may be used against him or her at trial. 147 Id. at 677. However, since these statements fell within the public safety exception to Miranda, under New York v. Quarles, 467 U.S. 649 (1984), the court did not err in refusing to suppress Newton’s statements. United States v. Newton, 369 F.3d 659, 677 (2d Cir. 2004). 148 United States v. Smith, 3 F.3d 1088 (7th Cir. 1993). 149 Id. at 1094. “We will not substitute our judgment for that of the officers as to the best methods to investigate.” Id. (quoting United States v. Boden, 854 F.2d 983, 993 (7th Cir. 1988)). 146 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 404 not to protect the police or the public . . . [but to] protect the fairness of the trial.”150 Thus, the court read Berkemer to stand for the proposition that Miranda rights may be triggered even if a defendant has not been subjected to an arrest or a de facto arrest.151 3. Eighth Circuit In United States v. Martinez, a suspect was placed in handcuffs, patted down for weapons, detained, and interrogated about his possession of weapons and cash.152 The court ruled that the encounter was a valid Terry stop, but nonetheless continued to analyze whether the suspect was in Miranda custody.153 After rejecting the government’s argument “that so long as the encounter remained a Terry stop, no Miranda warnings were required,”154 the court “followed the Supreme Court’s cue” and read Berkemer to imply that the dispositive consideration is not whether the encounter was a valid Terry stop, but what the circumstances of the stop were.155 The court ultimately determined that the detainee, despite not being under arrest during the lawful Terry stop, was entitled to Miranda warnings.156 4. Ninth Circuit In United States v. Kim,157 the Ninth Circuit held that the lower court correctly suppressed the defendant’s statements 150 Id. at 1097. Id. 152 United States v. Martinez, 462 F.3d 903, 906 (8th Cir. 2006). 153 Id. at 908 (“Whether Martinez was ‘in custody’ for purposes of Miranda after being handcuffed during the Terry stop is a separate question from whether that handcuffing constituted an arrest for which probable cause was required.”). 154 Id. at 909 (emphasis added). 155 Id. 156 Id. 157 United States v. Kim, 292 F.3d 969 (9th Cir. 2002). 151 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 405 during the course of a Terry stop because “under the totality of circumstances, a reasonable person in Kim’s circumstances would not have felt free to leave,” and therefore Kim was in Miranda custody.158 The court ruled so, despite the fact the defendant was not under arrest, because “the circumstances during the questioning of the defendant warranted advising [her] of her rights.”159 5. Tenth Circuit In United States v. Perdue,160 police conducting an investigative stop ordered the defendant and his fiancée to get out of their stopped car and lie face down.161 The officers drew their guns as the defendant made various statements regarding marijuana in his vehicle.162 The defendant appealed the district court’s decision not to suppress his statements, challenging the lower court’s conclusion that since he was interrogated during a valid Terry stop, Miranda warnings were not required.163 The Perdue court concluded that the district court “merged several distinct constitutional inquiries into one.”164 The court first held that the officer’s investigative stop of Perdue was a valid Terry stop.165 Next, the court acknowledged that Miranda rights might be implicated during a valid Terry stop because “[p]olice officers must make a choice—if they are going to take highly intrusive steps to protect themselves from danger, they must similarly provide protection to their suspects by advising 158 Id. at 978. Id. at 973. 160 United States v. Perdue, 8 F.3d 1455 (10th Cir. 1993). 161 Id. at 1458. 162 Id. at 1459. 163 Id. at 1461. 164 Id. 165 Id. at 1463. The court concluded that under the circumstances, the use of drawing their weapons and displaying some force was reasonable. Id. at 1462. The court also noted that this conduct “border[ed] on an illegal arrest.” Id. 159 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 406 them of their constitutional rights.”166 Because “[a] reasonable man in Mr. Perdue’s position could not have misunderstood the fact that if he did not immediately cooperate, his life would be in danger . . . [and] [a]ny reasonable person in Mr. Perdue’s position would have felt completely at the mercy of the police,” Perdue was in Miranda custody.167 Thus, contrary to the categorical rule adopted by the First and Fourth Circuits, the above circuits have adopted an independent approach by which the Fourth and Fifth Amendment issues are analyzed separately. IV. THE INDEPENDENT APPROACH HAS IT RIGHT Ultimately, evaluating Miranda custody separately and distinctly from the legality of the underlying Terry stop best balances law enforcement interests with suspects’ Fourth and Fifth Amendment rights. The First and Fourth Circuits’ categorical rule that Terry detainees are not in Miranda custody ignores the extension of Terry stops from a simple stop-and-frisk to police seizures that include drawn weapons, limited force, 168 interrogation, and detention. As a result, their approach fails to recognize that these intrusive techniques approach precisely the sort of coercive atmosphere that sparked the need for Miranda’s prophylactic rule. Alternatively, the independent approach, adopted by the Second Circuit and others, supports the policy justifications behind Terry and Miranda. This approach, coupled with courts continuing their efforts to clarify what restraints constitute Miranda custody and applying the 169 public safety exception promulgated in New York v. Quarles to Terry stops, minimizes burdens on law enforcement. 166 167 168 169 Id. at 1465. Id. (quoting United States v. Berkemer, 468 U.S. 420, 438 (1984)). See generally id. at 1462. New York v. Quarles, 467 U.S. 649 (1984). ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 407 A. The Second Circuit’s Approach Best Balances Suspects’ Rights with Law Enforcement Interests Newton’s approach, shared by the Seventh, Eight, Ninth, and Tenth Circuits,170 displays more sensible constitutional law by acknowledging and accepting the increasingly coercive nature of the Terry stop and applying distinct Miranda analysis without disturbing it. First, an independent approach concedes that different values underlie Terry and Miranda. Terry values the balance between an individual’s right to privacy against law enforcement’s goal of public safety.171 Miranda values a suspect’s privilege against 172 self-incrimination. Just as a prophylactic rule protecting a person’s Fifth Amendment privilege against self-incrimination is distinct from a person’s Fourth Amendment right against unreasonable search and seizure, so too should Miranda custody analysis be distinct from Fourth Amendment reasonableness. Put simply, just because a Terry stop may be reasonable, the police officer’s conduct may still (lawfully) rise to the level imagined by Chief Justice Warren in Miranda. To disregard the possible applicability of Miranda warnings to this type of Terry stop ignores the values that motivated Miranda. Second, in Miranda, the Court held that warnings are not just applied to arrest custody, but also to custodial detentions that detain the suspect in any significant way.173 While Berkemer held that routine traffic stops do not rise to the level of detention imagined by Miranda,174 the facts of Berkemer are distinguishable from the ultra-coercive Terry stops described in Newton and Perdue. While these coercive Terry stops may still not constitute de facto arrests, their use of limited force, drawn weapons, handcuffs, and extended duration certainly resemble the compelling environment of an arrest more than a traffic stop. 170 171 172 173 174 See supra Part III(B). Terry, 392 at 23–28. Miranda v. Arizona, 384 U.S. 436, 479 (1966). Id. at 444. Berkemer v. McCarty, 458 U.S., 420, 437–40 (1984). ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 408 Third, categorical denial of Miranda to Terry stops assumes, incorrectly, that all Terry stops are intrusions on personal liberty not worthy of the prophylactic protections of Miranda.175 Just like not all arrests are the sort of police-dominated stationhouse interrogations imagined by Miranda, not all Terry stops are the minor intrusions on personal liberty imagined by Terry. Fourth, Chief Justice Warren, in Miranda, failed to actually define “custody” as an “arrest.”176 In fact, he failed to define “custody” at all.177 It is reasonable to conclude that the two were not intended by the Court to be synonymous. Analogously, just as Miranda was framed in the in-station police-dominated environment, Miranda warnings are now given to all arrests regardless of the degree of coerciveness of the environment. Since Miranda left the confines of the police station, it is not incongruous to argue it should leave the confines of a formal or de facto arrest.178 Finally, the Berkemer Court admitted that a bright-line rule stating Miranda does not apply until a suspect is officially placed under arrest would “enable the police to circumvent the constraints on custodial interrogations established by Miranda.”179 By denying Miranda’s application to Terry stops, police may find incentive to put off an arrest until after they have finished questioning a detainee. B. More Concretely Define the Scope of Miranda Custody Courts applying the independent approach must clarify what restraints actually constitute Miranda custody in order to minimize the burdens on law enforcement that include overcomplication and exclusion of evidence at trial. In Newton, the 175 Richard A. Williamson, The Virtues (and Limits) of Shared Values: The Fourth Amendment and Miranda’s Concept of Custody, 1993 U. ILL. L. REV. 379, 409 (1993). 176 Miranda, 384 U.S. 436. 177 Id. 178 See generally Williamson, supra note 175 (explaining the expansion of Miranda warnings beyond the traditional bounds of a formal arrest). 179 Berkemer, 458 U.S. at 441. ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 409 Second Circuit noted the “difficulty of determining ‘custody’ for purposes of Miranda and the Supreme Court’s lack of clear guidance on the issue.”180 At least one commentator has noted that when Miranda was decided, the legal terms “custody” and “arrest” meant roughly the same thing.181 This is no longer the case,182 in part due to exceptions to the warrant requirement and increasing ambiguity as to the role and permissible substance of a Terry stop. If a court accepts the proposition that Miranda custody can be achieved without an arrest, it is irresponsible to expect police officers to determine when to deliver Miranda warnings based on an admittedly vague standard, and then punish their incorrect judgment by excluding statements made during the encounters. In Miranda, the Court stated specifically that an “understanding of the nature and setting of [an] in-custody interrogation is essential to” their decision.183 Since the nature and setting of interrogations has changed,184 so must the analysis of whether Miranda applies. While the Second and Eighth Circuits have identified factors to determine whether Miranda custody was met,185 these 180 United States v. Newton, 369 F.3d 659, 670 (2d Cir. 2004) (citing Cruz v. Miller, 255 F.3d 77, 86 (2d Cir. 2001)). 181 Mark A. Godsey, When Terry Met Miranda: Two Constitutional Doctrines Collide, 63 FORDHAM L. REV. 715, 741 (1994). 182 Id. 183 Miranda v. Arizona, 384 U.S. 436, 445 (1966). 184 Supra Part II(A)(i). 185 See Newton, 369 F.3d at 674 (“Among the facts generally deemed relevant are (1) the length of time involved in the stop; (2) its public or private setting; (3) the number of participating law enforcement officers; (4) the risk of danger presented by the person stopped; and (5) the display or use of physical force against the person stopped, including firearms, handcuffs, and leg irons.”); United States v. Brown, 990 F.2d 397, 399 (8th Cir. 1993) (“(1) [W]hether the suspect was informed at the time of questioning that the questioning was voluntary, that the suspect was free to leave or request the officers to do so, or that the suspect was not considered under arrest; (2) whether the suspect possessed unrestrained freedom of movement during questioning; (3) whether the suspect initiated contact with authorities or voluntarily acquiesced to official request to respond to questions; (4) whether strong arm tactics or deceptive stratagems were ISAACS REVISED.DOC 410 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY multiple-factor analyses do little to assist the police officer engaging in a spontaneous and fast on-the-street encounter. Common sense suggests that police officers asked to rely on such a multiple-factor analysis would in fact be relying on intuition—where the cost of an officer’s wrong intuition is exclusion,186 a firmer standard, designed for the needs of police officers conducting rapidly developing investigative stops, is imperative. C. The Application of Quarles’ Public Safety Exception to Terry Stops Quarles’ public safety exception permits statements made to police, before the reading of Miranda warnings, to be included as evidence in an ensuing criminal trial so long as the questioning by the police was reasonably prompted by an immediate concern for the safety of the police or public.187 Given this exception, Miranda warnings are only required during a Terry stop when police interrogation is targeted at gathering evidence, and not required before questions directed at resolving an immediate threat to public and officer safety. The public safety exception mitigates burdens on law enforcement, bolsters the policies that justify Terry stops, and balances the detainee’s civil right to Miranda warnings against public and officer safety. In Quarles, a woman told two police officers in Queens, New York, that she was just raped; she described the man and told the officers he had just entered a nearby supermarket and 188 was armed. An officer reached the suspect in the store, frisked him, and discovered an empty shoulder holster.189 After employed during questioning; (5) whether the atmosphere of the questioning was police dominated; or, (6) whether the suspect was placed under arrest at the termination of the questioning.”). See also supra Part II(A)(i). 186 Mapp v. Ohio, 367 U.S. 643, 660 (1961) (disallowing the admission of evidence seized pursuant to an unlawful search during the trial of the subject of the unlawful search). 187 New York v. Quarles, 467 U.S. 649 (1984). 188 Id. at 651–52. 189 Id. ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 411 handcuffing him, the officer asked where the gun was—the suspect “nodded in the direction of some empty cartons and responded, ‘the gun is over there.’”190 The officer then placed the suspect under arrest and read him his Miranda rights.191 Quarles sought to have his statement, “the gun is over there,” excluded from trial because the officer had not yet given him his Miranda warnings.192 The Court noted that this case presented a situation where “concern for public safety must be paramount to adherence to the literal language of the prophylactic rules enunciated in Miranda,”193 and thus established a “public safety” exception to Miranda.194 The Court was largely persuaded by the realities of the encounter:195 first, in apprehending the suspect, the officers were confronted with the immediate necessity of discovering the location of a hidden gun in a public place. The situation posed dangers to the public because an accomplice might use it, or a customer or employee may find it.196 Second, the Court noted that if the police are “required to recite the familiar Miranda warnings before asking the whereabouts of the gun, suspects in Quarles’ position might well be deterred from responding.”197 The police officer “needed an answer to his question not simply to make his case against Quarles but to insure that further danger to the public did not result from the concealment of the gun in a public area.”198 190 Id. Id. 192 See id. 193 Id. at 653. 194 Id. at 655. The Court also clarified that the availability of this exception does not depend upon the individual motivations of the police. Id. at 656. “In a kaleidoscopic situation such as the one confronting these officers, where spontaneity rather than adherence to a police manual is necessarily the order of the day, the application of the exception which we recognize today should not be made to depend on post hoc findings at a suppression hearing concerning the subjective motivation of the arresting officer.” Id. 195 See id. at 657. 196 Id. 197 Id. 198 Id. (emphasis added). 191 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 412 Third, the Court recognized the importance of an easily workable rule “to guide police officers, who have only limited time and expertise to reflect on and balance the social and individual interests involved in the specific circumstances they confront.”199 Finally, while admitting that the present exception muddied Miranda’s bright-line rule, the Court concluded that this exception would not be difficult for police officers to apply because in each case police should be able to distinguish between questions necessary to secure personal or public safety and questions designed to elicit testimonial evidence.200 Thus, if Terry stops may rise to Miranda custody, then Quarles’ public safety exception permits police to interrogate Terry detainees regarding immediate threats to public or officer safety without first delivering Miranda warnings. Since Terry stops are limited to resolving officers’ reasonable suspicions that a suspect is dangerous or about to commit a crime, it is likely that Miranda warnings will be excepted under Quarles during most Terry stops. Indeed, the Newton court took such an approach, ruling that although the defendant was in custody during his interrogation, the questioning, which was directed to the recovery of a gun, fell within the Quarles public safety exception to Miranda and survived suppression.201 V. POSSIBLE CRITICISMS OF THE INDEPENDENT APPROACH A. The Costs of Issuing Miranda Warnings During a Terry Stop Outweigh the Benefits of the Prophylactic Rule Delivering Miranda warnings outside police station custodial interrogations can impose a significant cost and undermine 202 effective law enforcement: 199 Id. at 658 (citing Dunaway v. New York, 442 U.S. 200 (1979)). Id. at 658–59. 201 United States v. Newton, 369 F.3d 659, 677 (2d. Cir. 2004) (“[A]lthough Newton was in custody at the time of the challenged interrogation, questioning preliminary to the officers’ recovery of the charged firearm fell within the public safety exception to Miranda.”). 202 Note, Custodial Engineering: Cleaning Up The Scope of Miranda 200 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 413 [t]he mere recital of a Miranda warning formalizes a police-civilian interaction, which “may discourage citizens from cooperating with the police” . . . the recital of the warning and the detainee’s likely responses also delay an on-the-scene investigation, which may endanger the police and public . . . vague Miranda requirements jeopardize on-the-scene inquiries by causing uncertainty for the police officers who must administer the warning, the subject who receives it, and the courts that must review it . . . empirical evidence demonstrates that the Terry stop, frisk, and inquiry “should not be underestimated” as a deterrent to crime . . . it would threaten the unstructured and spontaneous nature of the Terry stop by formalizing the inquiry . . . it would block the proper execution of Terry by increasing the potential for unconstitutional delay during the brief stop . . . [all are] additional burdens on a Terry stop [that] would diminish its utility to law enforcement, and that result contradicts the recent efforts by courts to ensure that Terry stop, frisk, and inquiry remains a viable investigative option.203 The Warren Court recognized the burdens that law enforcement officials must bear,204 but remained adamant that the privilege against self-incrimination demanded certain 205 sacrifices. Thus, as Terry stops increasingly resemble the type of intrusive conduct the Miranda Court deemed serious enough to warrant a prophylactic rule, society must accept the sacrifices Miranda requires in the context of a Terry stop. Moreover, Quarles’ public safety exception mitigates these potential costs to safety by excepting questions directed towards resolving an immediate danger to public or officer safety. And while issuing Custody During Coercive Terry Stops, 108 HARV. L. REV. 665 (1995). 203 Id. (emphasis added). 204 Miranda v. Arizona, 384 U.S. 436, 481 (1966). 205 Id. at 479. “The quality of a nation’s civilization can be largely measured by the methods it uses in the enforcement of its criminal law.” Id. at 480, n.50 (citing Walter V. Shaefer, Federalism and State Criminal Procedure, 70 HARV. L. REV. 1, 26 (1956)). ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 414 Miranda warnings to a suspect may result in a failure to obtain evidence that would otherwise be collected, this cost to society is tempered by the prevention of the coercive means by which that evidence would have been obtained. B. Police Will Be Unable to Determine Whether They Have Placed a Suspect in Miranda Custody Before the permissible scope of a Terry stop expanded, the concepts of “arrest” and “custody” were closely related and Terry stops looked nothing like the behavior that constituted Miranda custody.206 Simply, officers knew Miranda warnings were not required during a lawful Terry stop. However, if Miranda applies to Terry stops, police officers must determine more than whether they have the requisite reasonable suspicion to conduct an investigative stop. In addition, they must consider whether the level of coerciveness with which they are conducting the search constitutes a custodial or non-custodial investigative stop for Miranda purposes, as well as whether their questions are directed at gathering evidence or resolving an immediate public safety suspicion. While these additional requirements complicate the orchestration of a Terry stop, they are necessary to balance the privilege against self-incrimination against the safety of the public and police officers. The difficulty of determining Miranda custody could be answered more easily with firmer guidelines from courts.207 Further, inquiry into the purpose of an officer’s questioning will not significantly impose on law enforcement efforts. As the Court explained in Quarles, “[w]e think police officers can and will distinguish almost instinctively between questions necessary to secure their own safety or the safety of the public and questions designed solely to elicit testimonial 208 evidence from a suspect.” 206 207 208 Williamson, supra note 175. See supra Part IV(B). New York v. Quarles, 467 U.S. 649, 658–59 (1984). ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 415 C. Terry Should Be Returned to Its Original Contours One commentator proposes resolving the Circuit split regarding the application of Miranda to Terry by returning “the Terry doctrine to its pre-expansion dimensions, and thereby diffus[ing] the tension that has recently been created between Terry and Miranda.”209 In short, the commentator argues that the best option to resolve the question of Miranda applicability to Terry is to reverse the expansion of Terry for two reasons: “(1) it is contrary to relevant Supreme Court authority, and (2) it has not been supported by persuasive or logical rationales.”210 Further “any frustration of police investigatory tactics caused by reversing Terry’s uncalled-for expansion would be counteracted by the efficiency and bright-line nature of the resulting rule.”211 This argument does not attack the soundness of the circuits’ differing views, but rather identifies a misstep by courts in permitting an environment to develop that is capable of fostering 212 the present disagreement. Although the simplicity of this approach is attractive, it ignores the reason that Terry expanded: an evolution of the type and rate of crime in this country since the Warren Court’s decisions.213 Regardless of the virtues of Terry’s expansion, courts must take steps to protect suspects Fifth Amendment rights.214 209 Godsey, supra note 181, at 741 (emphasis added). Id. 211 Id. at 747. 212 A response that fully addresses this argument is most appropriate for another case comment or article. 213 United States v. Michelletti, 13 F.3d 838, 844 (5th Cir. 1994). 214 United States v. Perdue, 8 F.3d 1455, 1465 (10th Cir. 1993) (“Police officers must make a choice–if they are going to take highly intrusive steps to protect themselves from danger, they must similarly provide protection to their suspects by advising them of their constitutional rights.”). 210 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 416 CONCLUSION In August of 2008, the Attorney General of New Mexico filed a petition for certiorari to the United States Supreme Court requesting review of the New Mexico Court of Appeals’ decision in State v. Snell,215 which adopted the independent approach and required Miranda warnings be read to a suspect detained in a squad car at a Terry traffic stop.216 The Court of Appeals stated that if a “motorist who has been detained pursuant to a traffic stop thereafter is subjected to treatment that renders him ‘in custody’ for practical purposes, he will be entitled to the full panoply of protections prescribed by Miranda.”217 Challenging this decision, the Attorney General cited to the First and Fourth Circuit’s approach in Trueber and Leshuk to support its position that New Mexico’s high court misapplied Berkemer and Miranda.218 The State’s petition acknowledged that [c]ourts and commentators alike have struggled with the manner in which the concept of arrest intersects the Fourth and Fifth Amendments . . . . The question seemingly left open by Berkemer, and on which both federal and state courts disagree, is whether Miranda extends to investigative detentions in which police officers use a greater than normal level of force in response to safety or other law enforcement concerns without effecting a de facto arrest.219 The petition was denied on December 1, 2008,220 and thus the question will continue to be reserved for states and lower courts. 215 New Mexico v. Snell, 166 P.2d 1106 (2007). Id. at 1111–12. 217 Snell, 166 P.3d at 1111. 218 Petition for Writ of Certiorari at 24, State v. Snell, 129 S. Ct. 626 (2008) (No. 08-196), available at 2008 WL 3833284. 219 Id. at 7. The petition also noted that the Second Circuit recognized a circuit split and broke from the First and Fourth Circuit in their approach to the application of Miranda to Terry stops. Id. 220 State v. Snell, 129 S. Ct. 626 (2008). 216 ISAACS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 11:44 PM MIRANDA’S APPLICATION TO TERRY STOPS 417 As the constitutional guidelines governing criminal procedures evolve, it is imperative that the new rules reflect the actual changes and practices of law enforcement. Mindful of the changes in nature of a Terry stop, courts ought to apply Miranda to the context of a lawful Terry stop that rises to the level of custody imagined by Miranda. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM HOW STREAMING AUDIO AND VIDEO CHANGE THE PLAYING FIELD FOR COPYRIGHT CLAIMS Melissa L. Morris* INTRODUCTION From reel-to-reel tape recorders to recordable compact discs (CDs), and from BetaMax tapes to writeable DVDs, technologically-savvy customers have always clamored for the newest technologies to record their favorite music and television 1 shows for personal use. The omnipresence of the Internet has provided users and entrepreneurs with an exciting yet sometimes confusing forum through which this accumulation of data can subject parties to liability for copyright infringement.2 As digital music and videos have become smaller and easier * J.D. Candidate, Brooklyn Law School, June 2010; B.A., Psychology and Italian, University of Texas, 2005. I would like to thank Joseph Cizmar, Allison Romosarek, and my parents, brother, grandparents, aunts, uncles, and cousins for all their support over the years. Without you all, I would not be where I am today and I cannot thank you all enough. Additionally, I would like to thank Vicky Lee for her invaluable help in the editing process. 1 See Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 423 (1984) (finding that owners of BetaMax Video Recorders engaged in widespread television recording). 2 See Katie Allen, Survey Finds Pirate Downloads at All-Time High and Set to Rise, GUARDIAN, July 30, 2007, http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/ 2007/jul/30/newmedia.musicnews; see also W. David Gardner, Top Cyberspace Lawyer Challenges RIAA’s Music-Sharing Lawsuits, INFORMATION WEEK, Nov. 18, 2008, http://www.informationweek.com/ story/showArticle.jhtml?articleID=212100538. 419 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 420 to transfer, illegal downloading through peer-to-peer services3 has steadily increased.4 In response to this trend, music and video copyright holders have utilized new and existing technology in an effort to combat widespread copyright infringement.5 One of the most promising technologies is the use of digital streaming.6 Through digital streaming, copyright owners can control access to their copyrighted material by deciding when and how the consumer accesses the audio and video content. Record companies have jumped at the chance to utilize such services as Pandora7 and Lala8 to allow users to “test” music before they buy it.9 Similarly, television companies, even non-broadcast television companies, have also utilized free, streaming services on their websites in order to provide users an avenue through which to see television shows in a controlled environment—often one laden with 3 Peer-to-peer (P2P) file sharing is a system whereby one user directly shares his or her files with another user, without the use of an intermediary. What is P2P File Sharing?, http://www.tech-faq.com/p2p-peer-to-peer-filesharing.shtml (last visited Oct. 3, 2009). Popular P2P systems formerly included “big names” such as, KaZaA, Morpheus, Grokster, and Napster. 4 See Patrick Foster, Young People Ignoring Attempts to Combat Illegal Music Downloading, TIMES ONLINE (London), Aug. 10, 2009, http://technology.timesonline.co.uk/tol/news/tech_and_web/the_web/article67 89409.ece. 5 See generally John Borland, Sony CD Protection Sparks Security Concerns, CNET, Nov. 17, 2005, http://news.cnet.com/Sony-CD-protectionsparks-security-concerns/2100-7355_3-5926657.html (using CD copy protection to prevent users from copying their CDs onto their computers); Peter Cohen, iTunes Store Goes DRM-Free, MACWORLD, Jan. 6, 2009 (using Digital Rights Management (DRM) as a way to prevent iTunes and Amazon users from playing—and thus sharing—songs on more than five computers). 6 For a discussion on streaming, see text accompanying notes 58–59. 7 About Pandora, http://www.pandora.com/corporate (last visited Oct. 3, 2009). 8 Lala, http://www.lala.com (last visited Oct. 3, 2009). 9 See, e.g., Anthony Ha, Internet Radio Reaches Deal with Record Industry, Pandora Saved, DIGITALBEAT, July 7, 2009, http://digital.venture beat.com/2009/07/07/internet-radio-reaches-deal-with-record-industry-pandora -saved/. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 421 advertisements—before the shows come out on DVD.10 However, although streaming music and video are cheap and pervasive, many consumers still want to “own” copyrighted materials.11 Record companies and television studios have been so successful at shutting down many popular free peer-to-peer services that consumers are using streaming feeds to obtain copies of copyrighted works at no cost.12 As a result, a host of programs have developed to allow a consumer to download streaming audio or visual works onto their computer for permanent use.13 This Note examines the various copyright implications for individuals who use programs to download streaming audio and video. Part I details the creation and development of the Internet and discusses how the music industry and its consumers have utilized technology to make music more accessible. Part II explains the copyright landscape in which both holders and potential infringers currently find themselves. This section outlines the rights of copyright holders and how they are most commonly protected and licensed. Part III surveys the potential liability for the developers of programs that allow users to download streaming audio and video. This section looks at previous litigation and examines potential liabilities in light of the unique developmental characteristics of the programs. Lastly, Part IV focuses on the potential liabilities of the end user of a program that allows the user to download streaming audio or video. This section analyzes prior litigation and examines whether a “fair use” argument justifies streaming audio and video. Ultimately, I propose that through careful crafting, software developers who create software that allows users to 10 See generally Louis Hau, Hulu’s Here, FORBES, Oct. 29, 2007, http://www.forbes.com/2007/10/28/hulu-online-video-biz-media-cx_lh_1029 bizhulu.html (stating that several television companies have gotten together to put much of their content on a single website); see also, e.g., NBC, www.nbc.com (last visited Oct. 3, 2009). 11 See generally Roy Furchgott, Free Music Downloads Without the Legal Peril, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 3, 2008 at C6. 12 Id. 13 Id. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 422 download streaming audio and video can avoid both direct liability and secondary liability for the infringement of their users. However, software users will continue to be liable for their direct infringement claims and will find themselves unable to escape liability by claiming they were using the music legally within the confines of copyright law. I. THE INTERNET AND MUSIC: THEN AND NOW Since its shadowy beginnings, the Internet has long been a 14 mysterious place for the common user. The Internet began in 1969 as a project started by the U.S. Department of Defense.15 The Advanced Research Projects Agency Network (ARPANET) was created to keep military facilities in metropolitan areas operational and in communication with each other in the event 16 of a nuclear attack. Over the next ten years, researchers at universities across the country devoted significant time and resources to developing an operational system through the use of radio waves, telephone lines, satellite communications, and Ethernet.17 From this work was born the Internet, a synthesis of ARPANET and the National Science Foundation’s network (NSFNET).18 Early public Internet Providers, known as online electronic information services, provided modem owners with the means to communicate with each other through a small group of computer servers.19 Through this system, users sent digital information 14 Mark Ward, How Well Can You Use the Web?, BBC NEWS, Mar. 29, 2004, http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/technology/3578149.stm. 15 AL KOHN & BOB KOHN, KOHN ON MUSIC LICENSING 1263 (3d ed. 2002). 16 Id. The ARPANET was in operation until 1989 and served as a primary testing site for many networking ideas, such as email and instant messaging. J.R. OKIN, THE INTERNET REVOLUTION: THE NOT-FOR-DUMMIES GUIDE TO THE HISTORY, TECHNOLOGY, AND USE OF THE INTERNET 53 (2005). 17 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1264. 18 Id. 19 Id. at 1261–62. Examples of early electronic information services are America Online (AOL), Prodigy, Microsoft Networks (MSN), and MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 423 (encoded as bytes in binary form) to a modem, which then converted it to an analog format that could be transmitted to another modem on the system operator’s server that reversed the process.20 By dialing the system operator’s specific Internet Protocol (IP) address, users could connect with each other, send emails, and communicate in real-time.21 In a process known as uploading, a user could send any type of computer file to the server of the system operator, where it would immediately be available to another user for download, or copying, onto the second user’s personal computer.22 The Internet, as it exists today, is a product of improvements to both the ARPANET system and the early electronic information services.23 In 1989, a computer scientist24 working at CERN (the European Organization for Nuclear Research) in Switzerland developed a new system that used hypertext to make information-sharing easier.25 This system came to be known as the World Wide Web and it enabled users to access documents on other computers by pointing and clicking on certain words or phrases of text, called hyperlinks.26 In 1993, computer CompuServe. Id. 20 Id. 21 Id. “Real-time” is a term describing communication that is instantaneous. What is Real Time?, http://www.webopedia.com/TERM/r/ real_time.html (last visited Dec. 3, 2008). Under such an operating system, the user will input data and the system will respond immediately. Id. 22 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1262. 23 See id. at 1261–68. 24 Tim Berners-Lee is a British computer scientist who completed the first successful communication between an http client and a server. OKIN, supra note 16, at 109. He is currently the director of the World Wide Web Consortium, a company that oversees the continual development of the Internet, and is involved in a myriad of other projects. Tim Berners-Lee, http://www.w3.org/People/Berners-Lee/ (last visited Nov. 30, 2008). In 2007, he was named Telegraph Magazine’s greatest living genius, along with Albert Hoffman, the creator of LSD. Top 100 Living Geniuses, TELEGRAPH, Oct. 30, 2007, http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/uknews/1567544/Top-100living-geniuses.html. 25 OKIN, supra note 16, at 100–01. 26 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1264–65. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 424 programmers at the University of Illinois developed the first “browser” software, a graphical user interface that navigated the World Wide Web.27 This program was known as Mosaic, and later became commercially available to the public as early versions of Netscape Navigator and Microsoft Internet Explorer.28 The creation of Mosaic, and others like it,29 have made the Internet accessible beyond its intended use of communication between researchers and military bases.30 Each website is now the functional equivalent of an early America Online (AOL) or Prodigy, enabling users to get more information from a wider number of sources.31 This has also meant astronomical developments in electronic commerce in the form of advertisements, retail, electronic publishing, financial services, music, and videos.32 The Internet has become more pervasive than ever before, and with this has come increased digital transmission of music.33 The earliest digital music files were large compared to today’s standards, with the average three-and-one-half minute song being approximately forty megabytes in size.34 However, in 27 OKIN, supra note 16, at 110. KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1265. 29 Today, there are a number of Internet web browsers, such as Microsoft’s Internet Explorer (used by 39.6% of users), Mozilla’s Firefox (46.6%), Google’s Chrome (7.1%), Apple’s Safari (3.6%), and Opera (2.2%). W3Schools, Browser Statistics, http://www.w3schools.com/ browsers/browsers_stats.asp (last visited Oct. 19, 2009). 30 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1265. 31 Id. at 1266. 32 Id. 33 In its 2009 report, the International Federation of the Phonographic Industry (IFPI) estimates that over one trillion songs are downloaded worldwide. INT’L FED. OF THE PHONOGRAPHIC INDUS., DIGITAL MUSIC REPORT 2009 (2009). The IFPI similarly estimates that over 95% of these downloads are illegal. Id. at 3. However, other studies have shown that, at least in the United Kingdom, the rate of legal downloads is almost equal to that of illegal downloads. Marc Beja, New Study Shows Decrease in Illegal Music Downloading, CHRONICLE OF HIGHER EDUC., July 13, 2009. 34 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1269. Today, that same three-and28 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 425 1996 a group of college students began to develop computer technology that took the large files from a CD and converted them into smaller, more accessible MP3 files.35 This new technology cut the time necessary to send and download a file using a fifty-six kilobyte modem36 from three hours to less than one hour.37 Software developers and entrepreneurs quickly created programs and websites to accommodate a growing demand for MP3 software and files.38 As this software became more widely distributed, the number of MP3s available worldwide grew, and most popular songs became available through servers, websites, and other programs.39 Users also began to use email programs and FTP40 servers to share music one-half minute song is a little over three megabytes, or about ninety percent smaller than its earlier counterpart. Id. 35 Id. at 1268. MP3 is short for Motion Pictures Experts Group 1, Audio Layer 3. Id. at 1269. It was created by the Motion Pictures Experts Group and the Fraunhofer-Gesellschaft Group as a way to compress audio and visual files. Id. The idea is that an MP3 file represents a filtered version of the larger file, with all of the inaudible binary information removed. Id. This results in a file size ninety percent smaller than the original. Id. 36 A fifty-six kilobyte modem is a modem that can send information at a maximum of 57,600 bits per second (bps). What is modem? http://www. webopedia.com/TERM/m/modem.html (last visited Dec. 3, 2008). These modems, and those with slower speeds, were originally the only modems through which an early Internet (AOL) user could access the operating system. KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1269. 37 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1269–70. Now that most computers access the Internet using faster connections, the download time for an MP3 can be just a few minutes. I. Fred Koenisgberg et al., Music, the Internet, and the Music Industry, in 1 MUSIC ON THE INTERNET: UNDERSTANDING THE NEW RIGHTS & SOLVING NEW PROBLEMS 11, 12–13 (2001). 38 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1270. 39 Id. at 1270–71. 40 FTP is short for File Transfer Protocol. DOUGLAS COMER, INTERNETWORKING WITH TCP/IP: PRINCIPLES, PROTOCOLS, AND ARCHITECTURES 499 (4th ed. 2005). Through FTP, a user could turn his computer into a server for files, instead of uploading them onto a third party’s server. Id. at 500–02. FTP servers can be dangerous, because although there are some protections, such as requiring passwords to access the server, a user running an FTP server that allows others to contribute files cannot control what files others put onto the server, including viruses. See id. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 426 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY with each other for no more than the cost of their internet service.41 As a way to save time and money, college students began developing programs that would search files available on different university networks and link a user to the file for download.42 The larger public demand for MP3s led to the creation of Napster, one of the earliest and arguably most pervasive programs to facilitate file sharing.43 The original version44 of Napster allowed users to share the MP3s available on their hard drives (regardless of how they were obtained) with users on other computers.45 Napster’s MusicShare software allowed each user to access an index of the files shared by all users connected at any given time, which could then be used to search for a specific title, artist, or keyword encoded in any of the original file names.46 The program would then connect to a server and pull up a list of matching results found on every other user’s computer, allowing a user to select a file to download.47 Users could use the results to connect to the computer of the file’s owner and download the file from his or her computer without paying a penny to either Napster or the copyright owner.48 It was not long before a group of nine record labels sued at 500–04. 41 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1270. 42 Id. at 1270–71. 43 Id. 44 This paragraph describes the features of the original Napster program. Napster was forced to drastically change its business model after the Ninth Circuit issued an injunction against the company in A&M Records, Inc. v. Napster, 239 F.3d 1004 (9th Cir. 2001). The current version of Napster functions more as a subscription service, where users pay a fee per month for unlimited access to streaming music and can download selected songs for an additional fee. See Napster, www.napster.com (last visited Dec. 2, 2008). 45 PAUL GOLDSTEIN, COPYRIGHT’S HIGHWAY: FROM GUTENBERG TO THE CELESTIAL JUKEBOX 165–66 (Stanford Univ. Press 2003) (1995). 46 Id. 47 Id. 48 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1272. For more on copyright ownership see infra, Part II. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 427 Napster for copyright infringement,49 and after an injunction shut Napster down, a host of similar programs were developed to replace it.50 Programs such as Grokster and Morpheus subjected users and their creators to liability for copyright infringement claims from large companies, such as Elektra Records51 and Capitol Records,52 and from even some small, independent recording labels.53 The large potential for, and incidence of, copyright infringement has led many audio and video copyright holders to utilize streaming technology in an effort to allow users to enjoy the content in a protected environment and to prevent them from obtaining exact digital copies of their works.54 Companies such as NBC, ABC, and Viacom have turned to streaming and have made much of their television content available without cost on their respective websites.55 In fact, large television companies 49 A&M Records, Inc., Geffen Records, Inc., Interscope Records, Sony Music Entertainment, Inc., MCA Records, Inc., Atlantic Recording Corp., Island Records, Inc., Motown Record Co., and Capitol Records, Inc. brought suit against Napster. Napster, 239 F.3d 1004. 50 Almost immediately after Napster shut down, Grokster and Morpheus were created in its stead. Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Studios, Inc. v. Grokster, Ltd., 545 U.S. 913, 923–24 (2005). Later, other programs such as KaZaA and LimeWire were also developed to help fill the demand for MP3s. Kazaa 3.0 vs. LimeWire 4.8.1, http://www.cdrinfo.com/Sections/Reviews/Specific. aspx?ArticleId=15064 (last visited Nov. 13, 2009). 51 See Elektra Entm’t Group, Inc. v. Santangelo, No. 06-CV-11520, 2008 WL 4452393 (S.D.N.Y. Oct. 1, 2008). 52 See Capitol Records, Inc. v. Foster, No. 04-CV-1569, 2007 WL 1223826 (W.D. Okla. Apr. 23, 2007). 53 See e.g., Nicolas Jondet, French Independent Music Labels Sue Morpheus Azureus, FRENCHLAW.NET, June 16, 2007, http://french-law. net/french-independent-music-labels-sue-morpheus-azureus.html; Yahoo! Settles Copyright Infringement Suit with EMI Music, BUSINESS WIRE, Oct. 2, 2003, http://www.allbusiness.com/media-telecommunications/movies-soundrecording/5763733-1.html. 54 Real Networks, Inc. v. Streambox, Inc., No. 2:99-CV-02070, 2000 WL 127311, at *2 (W.D. Wash. Jan. 18, 2000). 55 NBC’s list of streaming television shows are listed on its website and are free of cost. NBC, Video Library, http://www.nbc.com/Video/library/ (last visited Sept. 6, 2009). Similarly, ABC also has streaming shows MORRIS REVISED.DOC 428 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY have even begun to team up with each other to create streaming media conglomerates, like Hulu,56 in an effort to guarantee that users are watching the television companies’ versions of their copyrighted works.57 Streaming, an alternative to downloading, is accomplished by subdividing a file (usually an audio or video file) into small packets of information that each travel to a user’s computer.58 These small packets travel through different pathways and are placed in a temporary holding place, or “buffer,” which allows the user to listen or watch the file while his or her computer continues to retrieve packets of information.59 This differs from downloading, in that once a packet has been heard or viewed, it is erased from the buffer and replaced with a new packet of information.60 By the end of the file, there is nothing left in the buffer and all traces of the file have been removed from the computer.61 Through streaming, companies can control what content is available, whether consumers pay a fee to access the content, and the amount of advertising a consumer sees.62 Even with the proliferation of streaming and encryption technology, computer programmers have worked to develop programs that can be used to circumvent encryption protections in order to help users retain personal copies of copyrighted material.63 A simple Google search for “download streaming available on its website. ABC, Shows, http://abc.go.com/watch (last visited Sept. 6, 2009). Lastly, most of Viacom’s various television stations—such as Comedy Central and MTV—also stream full episodes of popular televisions shows on their websites. See Comedy Central, Exclusive Videos and Show Clips, http://www.comedycentral.com/funny_videos/index.jhtml (last visited Sept. 6, 2009); MTV, Free Music, Show and Movie Videos, http://www.mtv.com/videos/home.jhtml (last visited Sept. 6, 2009). 56 Hulu, http://www.hulu.com (last visited Nov. 13, 2009). 57 Hau, supra note 10. 58 W. Jonathan Cardi, Über-Middleman: Reshaping the Broken Landscape of Music Copyright, 92 IOWA L. REV. 835, 860–61 (2007). 59 Id. at 861. 60 See id. 61 Id. 62 See KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1258. 63 See Furchgott, supra note 11. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 429 audio” yields over eighteen million results64 and the results for “download streaming video” were almost twice as large.65 Free programs—like OrbitDownloader, KeepVid, and Audacity—and paid programs—like WM Capture—allow users to permanently record audio and/or video content while it is simultaneously being streamed to their computers.66 For copyright holders, this means that despite their best efforts to protect their works from infringement, any audio or video stream is permanently available, at the click of a button, to anyone with enough free time to learn to use the program.67 This accessibility could result in personal ownership of not only television shows with limited broadcast distribution, but also web content never meant for widespread release.68 64 A search was conducted using www.google.com for “download+streaming+audio” on Oct. 26, 2009 and retrieved over 18,400,000 results. 65 A search was conducted using www.google.com for “download+streaming+video” on Oct. 26, 2009 and retrieved over 29,400,000 results. 66 See, e.g., Audacity, http://audacity.sourceforge.net/ (last visited Oct. 24, 2009); KeepVid, http://keepvid.com/ (last visited Oct. 24, 2009); Orbit Downloader 2.0, http://www.orbitdownloader.com/ (last visited Oct. 24, 2009); WM Capture, http://www.wmrecorder.com/wm_capture.php (last visited Oct. 24, 2009). 67 See Furchgott, supra note 11. 68 This could include features like “The Office” webisodes, currently available through the NBC website, at http://www.nbc.com/The_Office/ episodes/. However, much of this content has not made it to DVD yet, likely because NBC has been hesitant to give the writers money for these shorts. Liz Gannes, Strike Really Over: The Office Webisodes Come Back, NEWTEEVEE, July 8, 2008, http://newteevee.com/2008/07/08/strike-reallyover-the-office-webisodes-come-back/. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 430 II. “MODERN”69 COPYRIGHT LAW Every song embodies two copyrightable works: a musical work and a sound recording.70 The “musical work” aspect of a song is the musical score and any written words.71 The songwriter is generally the copyright holder of the musical work, and he usually exercises his rights by assigning them to a music publisher72 or other group that issues such licenses.73 The “sound recording” aspect of a song is embodied in a particular artist’s version of that song.74 So, when Don Henley wrote75 and recorded “The Boys of Summer” in 1984,76 it embodied both a musical work and sound recording.77 The Ataris’s cover of “The 69 Many commentators have expressed distaste for modern copyright law as an outdated and outmoded regulatory regime. See Cardi, supra note 58, at 837; R. Anthony Reese, Copyright and Internet Music Transmissions: Existing Law, Major Controversies, Possible Solutions, 55 U. MIAMI L. REV. 237, 238–40 (2001). 70 Reese, supra note 69, at 240. 71 Id. 72 Music publishers historically functioned to connect song composers with artists, to secure recording deals, and to promote their writers’ songs. Cardi, supra note 58, at 840. However, modern music publishers are the primary contact when one is looking to obtain various licenses, including mechanical licenses among others. Id. at 841. 73 Id. at 841. The Harry Fox agency, which was established in 1927, is “the foremost mechanical licensing, collection, and distribution agency for U.S. music publishers.” Harry Fox Agency, About HFA, http://www.harry fox.com/public/HFAHome.jsp (last visited Nov. 13, 2009). It acts as the licensing arm for the National Music Publishers Association and wields great power in the musical industry. See Cardi, supra note 58, at 841; Reese, supra note 69, at 243 n.18. 74 Reese, supra note 69, at 241. 75 “Boys of Summer” was actually co-written by Don Henley and Mike Campbell, but in the name of simplicity, I will treat the song as if it were written by Henley alone. DON HENLEY, The Boys of Summer, on BUILDING THE PERFECT BEAST (Geffen Records 1984). 76 “The Boys of Summer” can be found on Don Henley’s 1984 album entitled Building the Perfect Beast. HENLEY, supra note 75. 77 Reese, supra note 69, at 240. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 431 Boys of Summer” in 2003,78 then, represented simply a new sound recording of Henley’s original musical work.79 This important distinction lays the groundwork for the exercise of each copyright holder’s rights in relation to the work.80 The Copyright Act,81 and its subsequent amendments,82 gives owners of a copyrighted work several general rights.83 These rights allow an owner to protect the work from theft, to protect from changes in technology, and to collect royalties on any uses of the work.84 The owner of a copyright enjoys a variety of rights, most importantly: to reproduce the work in phonorecords, to distribute copies of the work, to perform the works publicly, and to perform the work by means of digital 85 audio transmission. 78 “The Boys of Summer” can be found on The Ataris’s 2003 album entitled So Long, Astoria. THE ATARIS, The Boys of Summer, on SO LONG, ASTORIA (Sony 2003). 79 This is because instead of making a new and original musical work, The Ataris used the musical score and words of Henley’s version and created their own distinct sound recording. See generally Reese, supra note 69, at 240–42. 80 The same distinction holds true for television shows or movies. When a writer pens a screenplay or a television show, he—or his employer—owns the copyright to the script. STEPHEN BREIMER, THE SCREENWRITER’S LEGAL GUIDE 21 (Allworth Press, 3d ed. 2004). The writer can then assign his rights under copyright law to various people or companies. Id. at 22. For example, the writer of a screenplay can assign his right of adaptation to another screenwriter who wants to make a sequel to the first movie. Id. at 21. Additionally, he could assign his performance right to a motion picture company in order to make a movie from the original screenplay. Id. at 21– 22. The same writer would also be able to assign the right to public display of the work to the actors and actresses in the production, as they will be in the individual frames of the work. Id. at 22. 81 17 U.S.C.A. §§ 101–1332 (West 2009). 82 The Copyright Act was originally enacted in 1790 to protect books, maps, and charts. U.S. Copyright Office, Information Circular, http://www. copyright.gov/circs/circ1a.html (last visited Nov. 13, 2009). The Act has been overhauled and amended several times throughout history, most notably in 1831, 1909, and 1978. Id. 83 See generally 17 U.S.C.A. §§ 101–1332 (West 2009). 84 GOLDSTEIN, supra note 45, at 4, 26. 85 17 U.S.C. § 106(1), (3)–(4), (6) (2006). The right to perform the MORRIS REVISED.DOC 432 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY First, the right to reproduce gives a copyright owner the ability to produce and reproduce his original work.86 Thus in the case of Don Henley’s “The Boys of Summer,” Henley has the exclusive ability to reproduce his musical work and sound recording.87 Before the Ataris recorded their 2003 version, they had to obtain a mechanical license from Henley.88 Such a license permits the group to reproduce Henley’s original musical work and to create a new sound recording of the piece, of which they were the sole copyright owners.89 Such mechanical licenses are compulsory, meaning that the fees to obtain licenses are fixed.90 Once a copyright holder has authorized distribution, a user may use the song without obtaining permission from the holder, provided that the user puts the copyright holder on notice of his or her use and pays the statutory royalty.91 Conversely, a copyright holder, or his or her assignee, has complete discretion in deciding whether to authorize reproduction of a sound recording and in deciding how much to charge for the license, given that it is not subject to compulsory licensing.92 Second, the right to distribute copies of a work allows a copyright owner to profit from, and to control, the distribution of his or her original work.93 A copyright owner can issue a distribution license to authorize someone else to distribute the copyrighted work on his or her behalf.94 Generally, a copyright owner assigns ownership of his or her copyright to a music work publicly via digital transmission was added in 1995 through the Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings Act of 1995. Cardi, supra note 58, at 849–50. 86 Id. at 839. 87 See 17 U.S.C. § 106(1). 88 Most likely, they had to obtain the license from the Harry Fox Agency, or another group, to which he assigned his right. See supra notes 72–73. 89 Cardi, supra note 58, at 839. 90 The fee is currently fixed at 9.1 cents per song, or 1.75 cents for each minute of playing time, whichever is larger. 37 C.F.R. § 255.3 (2009). 91 Reese, supra note 69, at 242. 92 Id. at 243. 93 See Cardi, supra note 58, at 839. 94 Id. at 840. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 433 publisher who then contracts with a distributor for distribution of the work.95 The right of distribution is similarly subject to a compulsory licensing scheme.96 This means that after a user has authorized distribution, a potential distributor need only pay the statutory royalty97 and notify the owner before exercising unfettered access.98 Third, copyright owners are also given the exclusive right to perform the work publicly.99 For the copyright holder of a musical work or sound recording, this allows him or her to authorize or license another to perform the work publicly in a variety of contexts.100 This not only includes the ability to perform the song live in concert, but also the ability to play a recording of it in public, perhaps at a restaurant or bar.101 Unlike the rights of reproduction and distribution, performance rights are not subject to compulsory licenses.102 This means that for someone interested in performing a musical work or sound recording publicly, he or she cannot simply pay a royalty and put the owner on notice.103 In fact, the copyright holder decides what fee to charge (if any) and whether to even grant a license.104 Generally, performing-rights organizations (PROs)105 control the distribution of performance licenses.106 These PROs 95 Id. Id. at 843. 97 This royalty is also determined by 37 C.F.R. § 255.3. 98 Cardi, supra note 58, at 843. 99 17 U.S.C. § 106(4) (2006). 100 See KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 908. 101 Id. 102 See Cardi, supra note 58, at 843. 103 Reese, supra note 69, at 245. 104 Cardi, supra note 58, at 845. 105 PROs are non-profit organizations (or very low profit companies) composed of copyright holders. KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 905–07. These groups—the largest of which are the American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers (ASCAP), Broadcast Music Incorporated (BMI) and Society of European State Authors and Composers (SESAC)—formed to protect their members’ public performance rights from rampant infringement. Id. 106 Cardi, supra note 58, at 843. 96 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 434 have been avid enforcers of copyright infringement on behalf of the copyright holders they represent.107 Through the years, these organizations have shown up at small restaurants and even at Boy Scout campouts to enforce the holder’s right to public performance.108 For a potential licensee looking to obtain a public performance license for a musical work from a PRO, he or she will often be given only one option: purchasing a blanket license.109 A blanket license gives the licensee the entitlement to publicly perform any sound recording assigned to the PRO.110 With their large market shares,111 PROs provide radio stations with easy access to licenses allowing them to play a wide variety of music.112 However, this arrangement can cost as much as two percent of a station’s gross receipts.113 For smaller businesses, many PROs offer annual flat fees, which can also be costly.114 Lastly, copyright owners are given the right to perform the work digitally.115 This relatively new right arose out of concerns from the music industry about the ever-increasing ability of radio stations and other users to perform copyrighted music over the Internet without paying royalties to the copyright owner.116 Congress responded by passing the Digital Performance Right in Sound Recordings Act of 1995 (DPRSRA), which gave copyright owners the right to perform their works digitally.117 Digital performance rights give the copyright holder the 107 Id. at 844. Noah W. Bailey, ASCAP Can Cripple Small Venues, DALLAS OBSERVER, Jan. 9, 2008. 109 Cardi, supra note 58, at 845. 110 Id. 111 ASCAP represents fifty-four percent of the market, BMI represents forty-three percent of the market, and SESAC represents an additional three percent. Id. at 843–44. 112 Id. at 849. 113 Id. 114 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1307. 115 17 U.S.C. § 106(6) (2006). 116 Cardi, supra note 58, at 850. 117 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1256. 108 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 435 exclusive right “to perform [or authorize performance of] the copyrighted work publicly by means of a digital audio transmission.”118 Unlike reproduction and distribution licensing, this right is not subject to compulsory licensing regulations.119 Some publishing companies—including the Harry Fox Agency120—have interpreted this to mean that streaming services are now subject to licensing requirements and therefore have begun to charge large royalties.121 In fact, the Harry Fox Agency has taken the position that royalties should be paid for each packet of information that is retained in the buffer during a streaming audio or video transmission.122 III. LIABILITY OF SOFTWARE COMPANIES A. Direct Liability Under the Copyright Act,123 copyright infringement occurs if: (1) the work is original, sufficiently creative, and within the subject matter of copyright;124 (2) the plaintiff is the registered owner of a valid copyright;125 and (3) the defendant has copied 118 17 U.S.C. § 106(6). See 17 U.S.C.A. §§ 114–15 (West 2009). 120 For more information on the Harry Fox Agency, see supra note 73. 121 Cardi, supra note 58, at 862. 122 Harry Fox Agency, Licensee Digital Licensing, http://www.harryfox. com/public/licenseeServicesDigital.jsp (last visited Nov. 13, 2009). The Harry Fox Agency currently distributes mechanical licenses for various digital formats, including permanent digital downloads, limited use downloads (i.e. those that can be played 10 times and then no longer work), and streaming music. Id. 123 17 U.S.C.A. §§ 101–1332 (West 2009). 124 17 U.S.C. § 102 dictates which works are copyrightable—in that “original work[s] of authorship, fixed in a tangible form, [that] come within the subject matter of copyright law” are copyrightable. 17 U.S.C. § 102 (2006). There must be some form of creativity on the part of the author, although the threshold is low and the copyrighted work need not be novel. Feist Publ’ns v. Rural Tel. Serv. Co., 499 U.S. 340, 345 (1991). 125 Feist, 499 U.S. at 361. 119 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 436 constituent elements of the work that are copyrightable.126 The third element, copying, is established if the owner can show: (1) direct copying of the work; (2) access to the copyrighted work and substantial similarity between the plaintiff’s work and the defendant’s work; or (3) striking similarity of the works.127 However, programs and devices that allow users to infringe on copyrighted works cannot be held directly liable under a theory of copyright infringement for those infringing activities.128 In 1999, Congress passed the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA)129 to combat the growing problem of copyright infringement and the growing number of computer programs facilitating this infringement.130 The DMCA prohibits persons from “circumvent[ing] a technological measure that effectively controls access to a work . . . .”131 The statute was initially used to prevent modifications to Sony PlayStations that allowed users to modify the rules of a game and to play unauthorized copies of video games.132 It has also been used to combat a decryption program that allowed users to circumvent encryption protection on DVDs, thereby enabling them to copy the content of their DVDs onto their computer hard drive.133 The DMCA does not hold such “persons” liable for their circumvention of technological measures under a traditional copyright infringement theory.134 Instead, a “person” may be 126 Segrets, Inc. v. Gillman Knitwear Co., 207 F.3d 56 (1st Cir. 2000); T.B. Harms Co. v. Eliscu, 339 F.2d 823 (2d Cir. 1964). These rights are granted to him under 17 U.S.C. § 106. 127 Towler v. Sayles, 76 F.3d 579 (4th Cir. 1996); Robert R. Jones Assoc. v. Nino Homes, 858 F.2d 274 (6th Cir. 1988). 128 Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Studios, Inc. v. Grokster, Ltd., 545 U.S. 913, 930 (2005); Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 434 (1984). 129 17 U.S.C. § 1201 (2008). 130 KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1256. 131 17 U.S.C. §1201(a) (2008). 132 Sony Computer Entm’t Am. Inc. v. Gamemasters, 87 F. Supp. 2d 976, 987–88 (N.D. Cal. 1999). 133 Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Reimerdes, 82 F. Supp. 2d 211 (S.D.N.Y. 2000). 134 17 U.S.C. § 1201(a) (2006). MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 437 found to have violated the statute if they (1) have circumvented a technological measure (2) that effectively worked to control access to (3) a work protected under the Copyright Act.135 A “person” circumvents a technological measure when he works to “descramble a scrambled work, to decrypt an encrypted work, or otherwise avoid, bypass, remove, deactivate, or impair a technological measure, without the authority of the copyright owner.”136 Further, a technological measure “‘effectively controls access to a work’ if the measure, in the ordinary course of its operation, requires the application of information, or a process or a treatment, with the authority of the copyright owner, to gain access to the work.”137 For programs that are designed to allow their users to obtain copies of streaming audio or video, liability under the DMCA will rest with how the program and its advertising are 138 139 designed. Real Networks, Inc. v. Streambox, Inc. was one of the first cases involving liability under the DMCA. Real Networks concerned an early program that allowed users to directly download streaming audio or video from Real Player.140 That program was named StreamboxVCR,141 and it worked by tapping into the information stream and circumventing specific encryption measures instituted by Real Player to protect copyrighted material.142 More specifically, StreamboxVCR “spoke” to Real Player’s encryption mechanism, thereby allowing its users to download previously protected streaming 135 Id. Id. § 1201(a)(3)(A). 137 Id. § 1201(a)(3)(B). 138 See, e.g., Real Networks, Inc. v. Streambox, Inc., No. 99-CV-2070, 2000 WL 127311 (W.D. Wash. Jan. 18, 2000). 139 Id. 140 Real Player is a media player developed by Real Networks, Inc. and introduced in 1995 to play a variety of audio and video files on multiple operating systems. Real Neworks, About Us, http://realnetworks.com/aboutus/index.aspx (last visited Oct. 25, 2009). 141 StreamboxVCR was a program created by Streambox, Inc. to allow its users to circumvent protective features of Real Player and to download videos from a streaming feed. Real Networks, 2000 WL 127311 at *4. 142 Id. at *4. 136 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 438 files.143 Real Networks, Inc. maintained that this feature of StreamboxVCR subjected the program to liability under the DMCA.144 The Western District of Washington agreed and found that these features circumvented technological measures of Real Networks, Inc. that were designed to control access to copyrighted works, thereby subjecting Streambox, Inc. to liability.145 Since Real Networks, programs have developed to avoid the problems faced by StreamboxVCR.146 Instead of piggybacking onto or circumventing encrypted streaming audio or video, many new programs operate differently by acting like a tape recorder or VCR.147 For example, programs like WM Capture148 and 149 CamStudio allow users to record whatever is playing over the speakers or on the screen at any particular moment.150 While seemingly more primitive, these programs often allow users to modify the settings of the program to maximize the quality of the finished download.151 Some audio programs, such as Audacity,152 allow a user to control the amount of outside noise recorded and the amount of noise that is recorded from computer-generated sounds, thus easily minimizing external noises and allowing the program to record only internal noises.153 Further, video programs—like WM Capture—go as far as to actually allow the user to select the exact window they wish to record, thus avoiding a border of non-video content.154 143 Id. Id. 145 Id. at *9. 146 See Furchgott, supra note 11. 147 See Audacity, supra note 66; CamStudio Suite, http://camstudio.org/ (last visited Nov. 13, 2009); WM Capture, supra note 66. 148 WM Capture, supra note 66. 149 CamStudio Suite, supra note 147. 150 WM Capture, supra note 66; CamStudio supra note 147. 151 See, e.g., Audacity: Features, http://audacity.sourceforge.net/about/ features (last visited Sept. 30, 2009). 152 Audacity, supra note 66. 153 Id. 154 WM Capture, supra note 66. 144 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 439 While courts have not decided issues related to whether the new generation of programs would be directly liable under the DMCA, it is unlikely that they will be held liable. Even a broad reading of the DMCA that is consistent with case law—such as Real Networks, Inc. v. Streambox, Inc.—indicates that these programs do not violate the statute because they do not interfere with the data stream, but rather copy it: an activity not prohibited by the DMCA as currently written.155 Many copyright holders have attempted to remedy illegal downloading of their copyrighted works by making them available for little or no cost through their own protected services.156 Consequently, copyright holders have put in place technological measures that would effectively control access to a work, such as developing encryption software that prevents a user from downloading the stream directly from the host site.157 158 The copyright holders do not flout their security measures. Instead, NBC and other networks offer users some downloadable content, but require users to stream the larger body of works that are unavailable for download.159 For this reason, courts will find that any such copyright holder will have made out the second and third elements of a claim under the DMCA.160 155 See supra notes 147–154 and accompanying text. See, e.g., The Complete List of Sites to Stream TV From, http://www.randomn3ss.com/the-complete-list-of-websites-to-stream-full-tvshows-and-movies-from/ (last visited Sept. 7, 2009). 157 The concept is similar to that of Real Player, given that they specifically developed a “Copy Switch” that allowed the original copyright owner to determine whether to allow the user to download the stream or to simply watch the stream through Real Player. Real Networks, Inc. v. Streambox, Inc., No. 99-CV-02070, 2000 WL 127311, at *2 (W.D. Wash. Jan. 18, 2000). 158 See Jacqui Cheng, Hulu Tries HTML Encoding Trick to Protect Streaming Content, ARS TECHNICA, Apr. 2, 2009, http://arstechnica.com/ media/news/2009/04/hulu-tries-html-encoding-trick-to-protect-streamingcontent.ars. 159 NBC, Frequently Asked Questions, http://www.nbc.com/frequentlyasked-questions/?section=video#video (last visited Nov. 13, 2009). 160 The second and third elements of a DMCA claim are (1) that the “person” (2) effectively worked to control access (3) to a work protected 156 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 440 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY However, the copyright holder must still show that the program acted to circumvent a technological measure.161 As defined by statute, in order to “circumvent a technological measure,” the program must work to “descramble a scrambled work, to decrypt an encrypted work, or otherwise avoid, bypass, remove, deactivate, or impair a technological measure, without the authority of the copyright owner.”162 Programs with features similar to WM Capture, which allow users to record what they see on their computer screens, do not work by descrambling a scrambled work or decrypting an encrypted work, as did StreamboxVCR.163 Further, they are specifically crafted not to remove, deactivate, or impair a technological measure put in place by a copyright holder.164 Thus, a court would turn to whether such programs act to “avoid, bypass, remove, deactivate, or impair a technological measure” put in place by the copyright holder. Given that these programs do not work to remove, deactivate, or impair any technological measures, courts will focus solely on whether they act to “avoid” or “bypass” a technological measure.165 Courts that have reached the issue have routinely found the technological measures are only “avoided” or “bypassed” when the allegedly infringing programs act to tell the technological measures not to function.166 WM Capture does under the Copyright Act. 17 U.S.C. § 1201(a) (2006). It is clear that programs such as Audacity and WM Capture function in a way to download (or “control access”) to copyrighted audio and video (or, “works protected under the Copyright Act”). See Audacity Features, supra note 151; WM Capture, supra note 66. 161 17 U.S.C. § 1201(a). 162 Id. § 1201(a)(3)(A). 163 See WM Capture, supra note 66. 164 The makers of Audacity and WM Capture have designed their programs so that they do not specifically tamper with any encryption technology or other technological measure put in place by the copyright holder to protect their work from infringement. See generally Audacity, supra note 66; WM Capture, supra note 66. 165 See 17 U.S.C. § 1201(a)(3)(A). 166 See, e.g., 321 Studios v. Metro Goldwyn Mayer Studios, Inc., 307 F. Supp. 2d 1085 (N.D. Cal. 2004). MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 441 not work to tell the technological measures not to function, but instead works alongside the technological measures to produce a copy of the work. For this reason, without legislative intervention, carefully designed programs can likely avoid liability under the DMCA. In fact, some count on it.167 B. Secondary Liability Under copyright law, programs and devices that allow users to infringe on copyrighted works cannot be held directly liable under a traditional theory of copyright infringement for those infringing activities.168 Therefore, courts have traditionally found programs or machines facilitating copyright infringement to be liable for the actions of their users under a theory of secondary liability.169 Under a secondary liability theory, programs that allow users to download streaming audio or video can be held liable under theories of contributory or inducement liability.170 1. Contributory Liability Contributory liability occurs when one intentionally induces or encourages the direct infringement of another.171 Unlike its counterpart, the Patent Act,172 the Copyright Act does not have a specific provision to punish contributory infringers.173 In Sony Corporation of America v. Universal City Studios, Inc., the 167 WM Capture claims on its website to be “100% legal worldwide.” WM Capture, supra note 66. 168 Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Studios, Inc. v. Grokster, Ltd., 545 U.S. 913, 929–30 (2005) (citing Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 434–86 (1984)). 169 Grokster, 545 U.S. at 930. 170 See id. at 930, 935. 171 Id. at 930 (citing Gershwin Pub. Corp. v. Columbia Artists Mgmt Inc., 443 F.2d 1159, 1162 (2d Cir. 1971)). 172 The Patent Act provides for a specific cause of action against those who actively induce infringement of a patent as an infringer himself. 35 U.S.C. § 271 (2006). 173 Sony, 464 U.S. at 435. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 442 Supreme Court found that because there was a close relationship between copyright and patent law, and because vicarious liability is found in nearly every area of the law, it was proper for the Court to “develop” a cause of action for contributory copyright infringement in absence of a statute.174 In Sony, Universal City Studios, Inc.—representing a conglomerate of television and movie copyright owners—brought suit against Sony to enjoin Sony’s sale and distribution of the BetaMax VTR (“BetaMax”).175 Sony manufactured and advertised BetaMax as a home recording device.176 An overwhelming majority of BetaMax owners reported using the machine to “time-shift,” or to record television programs for viewing again, or for the first time, at a later date.177 The Supreme Court held that a manufacturer could be held liable under a theory of contributory infringement if it was “in a position to control the use of copyrighted works by others and had authorized the use without permission from the copyright owner.”178 Further, the Court found that in patent law, contributory liability was confined to the knowing sale of an item that was specifically made for use to infringe on the patent.179 Analogizing to contributory liability, the Court found that an object could not contributorily infringe on the copyright of another if it was “capable of substantial non-infringing uses.”180 In Sony, the Court found that the BetaMax was capable of “substantially non-infringing uses” because it could be used to record programs without copyrights or programs whose owners 181 freely authorized recording. Under this standard, many of the programs today would avoid liability, as long as they are 174 175 176 177 178 179 180 181 See id. Id. at 420. Id. at 419–20. Id. at 424 n.4. Id. at 437–38. Id. at 440. Id. at 442. Id. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 443 capable of substantially non-infringing uses.182 Indeed, many recording programs are capable of such uses.183 Programs used to record streaming audio could be used to record class lectures, personal audio recordings, copyrighted audio for which the user has permission, or to record uncopyrighted audio. The same can be said for programs that allow the user to record streaming video. Coaches and teachers can use the feature to record for educational purposes; families can use the programs to edit their family videos; or users can record non-copyrighted materials or materials for which there is authorization. If a court could be persuaded that these uses are substantial, it would find that these programs are also not contributorily liable for the infringement of their users. 2. Inducement Liability Inducement liability occurs “when one induces commission of infringement by another, or ‘entic[es] or persuad[es] another’ to infringe.”184 The “classic” case of inducement liability is when a program or device advertises its infringing uses and thereby encourages others to commit violations.185 To be found liable through inducement theory, there must be clear evidence that the distributor of the product intended and encouraged it to be used to infringe on copyrights.186 In addition, the distributor must have knowledge that the product was used to infringe on the copyrights of others.187 In MGM v. Grokster, the Court found that Grokster, Inc. and StreamNetworks, Inc. distributed their programs (Grokster and Morpheus, respectively) with the intent that they be used to download copyrighted materials, in violation of the rights of the copyright holders.188 In addition, through 182 Id. See, e.g., Audacity, supra note 66; WM Capture, supra note 66. 184 Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Studios, Inc. v. Grokster, Ltd., 545 U.S. 913, 935 (2005) (quoting BLACK’S LAW DICTIONARY 790 (8th ed. 2004)). 185 Id. at 937. 186 Id. at 936–37. 187 See id. at 937. 188 Id. at 939–40. 183 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 444 advertisements and interoffice memoranda, the companies were found to have openly encouraged their users to infringe, even profiting through the use of streaming advertisements.189 Although Grokster and Morpheus had potentially non-infringing uses, it was clear that not only were they aware that users were downloading files illegally, but that ninety percent of files available through either program were available in violation of copyright laws.190 Newer programs, like Audacity and WM Capture, have developed in the wake of Grokster and have carefully crafted their programs to avoid the same problems faced by Morpheus and Grokster.191 Both Audacity, which advertises itself 192 exclusively as sound editing software, and WM Capture, which advertises itself as a way to “record video from ANY web site . . . [and] DVD[] playing on your [computer,]”193 are 194 cautious not to promote or encourage copyright infringement. There is no suggestion on the Audacity website or in the help section that the program could be used for infringing uses.195 In fact, WM Capture has a section that explicitly encourages users not to use its software for infringing purposes.196 Therefore, courts would be hard-pressed to find that these programs induced their users to use them in an illegal manner. However, if a program blatantly advertises its infringing uses, as did both Morpheus and Grokster,197 it is more likely to 189 Id. at 924–26. Id. at 922. 191 See Furchgott, supra note 11. 192 About Audacity, http://audacity.sourceforge.net/about (last visited Dec. 2, 2008). 193 WM Capture, supra note 66. 194 See About Audacity, supra note 192; WM Capture, supra note 66. 195 See Audacity, supra note 66; Audacity: Documentation and Support, http://audacity.sourceforge.net/help/ (last visited Nov. 13, 2009). 196 WM Capture, Legal Note, http://www.wmrecorder.com/wm_capture. php#legal (last visited Nov. 13, 2009). 197 Both Morpheus and Grokster not only advertised themselves as Napster replacements, but they also actively encouraged copyright infringement through their websites and web forums. Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Studios, Inc. v. Grokster, Ltd., 545 U.S. 913, 939–40 (2005). 190 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 445 be found liable for vicarious infringement.198 The more blatant the encouragement, the more likely the programmers will be found liable for the infringing uses of its users.199 IV. LIABILITY OF USERS A. Direct Liability Although the recording and television/movie industries have 200 instituted lawsuits against individual copyright infringers, they have focused mainly on college-aged students.201 Even now that the media industries have begun to work with Internet Service Providers (ISPs) to catch those who download illegally,202 pursuing litigation may prove to be unwise. On the one hand, most owners or assignees of audio or video copyrights could easily obtain a per se judgment in their favor against an alleged downloader.203 Record companies could and do subpoena records from ISPs in order to prove the necessary elements of a 198 Id. at 939–40. See generally id. (finding intent to promote copyright infringement through marketing directed toward previous users of Napster and the failure to develop “filtering tools” to reduce infringing activity). 200 See generally Elektra Entm’t Group, Inc. v. Santangelo, No. 06-CV11520, 2008 WL 4452393 (S.D.N.Y. Oct. 1, 2008); Capitol Records, Inc. v. Foster, No. 04-CV-1569, 2007 WL 1223826 (W.D. Okla. Apr. 23, 2007); Chris Gaither, Group Sues 261 Over Music-Sharing 46 are Accused in Boston Area, BOSTON GLOBE, Sept. 9, 2003, at A1; Kevin Maney, Music Industry Doesn’t Know What Else to Do As It Lashes Out at File Sharing, USA TODAY, Sept. 10, 2003 at 3B. 201 See Gardner, supra note 2. 202 Nate Anderson, No More Lawsuits: ISPs to Work with RIAA, Cut off P2P Users, ARS TECHNICA, Dec. 19, 2008, http://arstechnica.com/techpolicy/news/2008/12/no-more-lawsuits-isps-to-work-with-riaa-cut-off-p2pusers.ars. 203 The music industry has successfully brought suit against many alleged infringers, although most victories were by way of settlement or summary judgment. See John Borland, RIAA Sues 261 File Swappers, CNET NEWS, Sept. 8, 2003, http://news.cnet.com/2100-1023_3-5072564.html; David Kravets, File Sharing Lawsuits at a Crossroads, After 5 Years of RIAA Litigation, WIRED, Sept. 4, 2008. 199 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 446 copyright infringement claim, namely: the user had access and the file on the defendant’s computer was an exact copy of the original.204 Although there are defenses that may be effectively used to insulate the user from liability,205 it is unlikely that these defenses would help defendants in these lawsuits.206 Such lawsuits would allow the copyright owner to vindicate his ownership rights and would likely deter similarly situated users from infringing on the copyrights of others.207 On the other hand, such lawsuits garner enormous ill will toward the recording and film industries.208 Potential buyers will feel betrayed regardless of whether they routinely purchase copyrighted works, thus causing the recording and film industries to lose customers, especially young customers with years of consumer purchases ahead of them.209 Often, users and buyers use downloading as a way to “preview” songs and CDs,210 and if recording companies intend to prosecute indiscriminately,211 many customers will be even more hesitant to 204 See supra notes 124–25. The last element of a valid copyright, whether the holder had a valid copyright, should likewise not be difficult for a record company to prove. See supra text accompanying note 126. 205 See infra Part IV(B). 206 See id. 207 Infringement theory dictates that a user is likely to evaluate his or her illegal behavior in light of the relative risks of getting caught and the strength of the punishment. TOM R. TYLER, WHY PEOPLE OBEY THE LAW 56 (Paperback ed., 2006). Therefore, if the recording industry makes people believe that they are more likely to be caught, many users should—at least in theory—discontinue their illegal downloading. Id. 208 Alvin Chan, The Chronicles of Grokster: Who Is the Biggest Threat In the P2P Battle?, 15 UCLA ENT. L. REV. 291, 318–19 (2008). 209 Id. 210 There are a large amount of users who use downloading as a way to listen to music before they purchase a CD. File Swappers Buy More Music, BBC NEWS, July 9, 2003, http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/entertainment/music/ 3052145.stm. This seems to make sense considering that the price of a CD can approach $15-$18 and that sometimes only one or two songs are “singles” that play on the radio. See id. 211 The Recording Industry Association of America (RIAA) brought suit against thousands of individuals across the country, mostly college students and others who did not have the resources to properly defend themselves. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 447 pay for a CD with fifteen songs they have never heard before. B. Fair Use and Why It Would Not Protect Users Users that would otherwise be held liable for direct copyright infringement may sometimes escape liability by invoking the defense of “fair use.”212 The doctrine of fair use protects those from direct infringement liability who, in theory, do not harm a copyright owner by using the work for “fair” reasons, such as photocopying educational materials.213 The fair use doctrine was codified by Congress in 1976214 and was at issue in the landmark case of Sony Corporation of America v. Universal City Studios, Inc.215 In Sony, the Supreme Court balanced four factors to hold that “time-shifting”—using the BetaMax to record copyrighted shows for later, private viewing—constituted a fair use of a copyrighted work.216 In order for a court to find an infringing use to be a fair use, it must balance four factors: (1) the purpose and character of the use; (2) the nature of the copyrighted work; (3) the amount and substantiality of the portion used in relation to the copyrighted work as a whole; and (4) the effect of the use upon the potential market for or value of the copyrighted work.217 Gardner, supra note 2. However, the RIAA has not stopped with college students and has brought copyright infringement charges against many others, including a grandmother, Rhonda Crain, for rap and hip-hop songs a grandchild downloaded onto her computer. Eric Bangeman, RIAA v. Grandma, Part II: The Showdown That Wasn’t, ARS TECHNICA, Dec. 16, 2007. Ms. Crain has since settled. Id. 212 Charles B. Vincent, BitTorrent, Grokster, and Why Entertainment and Internet Lawyers Need to Prepare for the Fair Use Argument for Downloading TV Shows, 10 J. INTERNET L. 1, 11 (2007). 213 See Paul Goldstein, Symposium: Fair Use: “Incredibly Shrinking” or Extraordinarily Expanding?, 31 COLUM. J.L. & ARTS 433, 434 (2008). 214 17 U.S.C. § 107 (2006). 215 Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 454–55 (1984). 216 See id. at 450–56. 217 17 U.S.C. § 107. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 448 Factor 1: Purpose and Character of Use When examining the purpose and character of the infringing use, a court will focus on (1) whether the use simply replaces the original or transforms the original into a new work; and (2) whether the use is commercial or non-commercial.218 In A&M v. Napster, the Northern District of California found that downloading an audio or video file did not transform the work.219 The Ninth Circuit upheld this finding, in light of the reluctance of courts to find fair use when the original work is simply “transform[ed]” into the same work on another medium.220 The proper inquiry is whether the work is transformed by infusing it with new meaning or new understandings.221 That inquiry is not modified just because a user is downloading a streaming video or song instead of downloading a video or song from another user.222 Simply transforming the media from one format into another—such as transforming streaming bits of information into a single file— does not transform the work.223 A court will turn its attention next to whether the allegedly 218 17 U.S.C. § 107(1); see also Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 510 U.S. 569, 579 (1994). 219 See A&M Records, Inc. v. Napster, Inc., 114 F. Supp. 2d 896, 912 (N.D. Cal. 2000), aff’d 239 F.3d 1004, 1015 (9th Cir. 2000). 220 A&M Records, Inc. v. Napster, Inc., 239 F.3d 1004, 1015 (9th Cir. 2000); see also UMG Recordings, Inc. v. MP3.com, Inc., 92 F. Supp. 2d 349 (S.D.N.Y. 2000) (finding that reproduction of a CD into MP3 format does not constitute sufficient transformation to find fair use). 221 See Acuff-Rose, 510 U.S. at 579. 222 This would be because the ultimate product is still a perfect digital copy of the original work, just downloaded from another source. KOHN & KOHN, supra note 15, at 1245. 223 See A&M Records, 239 F.3d at 1015; see also Infinity Broad. Corp. v. Kirkwood, 150 F.3d 104, 108 (2d Cir. 1994) (finding that simply transmitting a former radio broadcast of a telephone line is not transformative); UMG Recordings, Inc. v. MP3.com, Inc., 92 F. Supp. 2d 349, 351 (S.D.N.Y. 2000) (finding that a song available on a CD was not transformed simply because it was also available on a website). MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 449 infringing use is commercial or non-commercial.224 While language in Sony suggests that a commercial user may never obtain fair use protection,225 courts have since found that commercial use weighs heavily against fair use, but is not dispositive.226 Courts consider financially motivated transactions, like a transaction to avoid paying the purchase price of a copyrighted item, to be a commercial use.227 The benefit from such a transaction need not be direct economic benefit, such as the saving of money or earning money from illegally distributing copyrighted works, but can be trade or other non-economic transaction benefits.228 In Napster, the Ninth Circuit found that both Napster and its users were commercially using the program by avoiding paying royalties to music companies in the form of record sales.229 However, in Sony, the Supreme Court found that users engaging in time-shifting of a broadcast program were non-commercial users.230 Commentators who suggest that downloading television shows is analogous to time-shifting using a BetaMax VTR231 not only neglect to take into account the key developments in technology,232 but also key aspects of the Sony holding. When a 224 17 U.S.C. § 107(1) (2006); see also Acuff-Rose, 510 U.S. at 578. Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 451 (1984) (“[E]very commercial use of copyrighted material is presumptively . . . unfair . . . .”). 226 Acuff-Rose, 510 U.S. at 584; see also A&M Records, 239 F.3d at 1015. 227 See A&M Records, 239 F.3d at 1015. 228 See id. 229 Id. 230 Sony, 464 U.S. at 449–50. 231 Vincent, supra note 212, at 12; see also Sheila Zoe Lofgren Collins, Sharing Television Through the Internet: Why the Courts Should Find Fair Use and Why It May Be a Moot Point, 7 TEX. REV. ENT. & SPORTS L. 79, 86 (2006). 232 Developments, such as the ability to watch television on the Internet, to record television onto a computer, to record using a Digital Video Recorder (DVR), or even to record television using a DVD recordable disc (DVD-R), have changed the way many television watchers view their televisions. See generally Intel, The Changing TV Experience, 225 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 450 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY copyright holder allows their copyrighted works to stream over the Internet, they are, in effect, giving anyone with a computer and Internet connection continuous, uninterrupted access to their work until it is taken down.233 Even when the work is taken down, users are almost guaranteed that even the least successful television show will come out on DVD.234 A user in 1984 had a larger necessity to “time-shift” a particular program—i.e. to record it for later viewing—because there was a significant chance he or she would never see that program again. Now a television watcher may purchase a DVD of virtually any program at a later date if he or she is patient enough.235 Allowing a user to download a streaming file would permit the user to completely circumvent the copyright holder’s wishes when choosing to restrict access to the public until the public release of the DVD.236 Further, the key to unlocking the Sony holding could be its focus on advertising and the revenues broadcast television earn as a result of making a quality television show.237 In 1984, BetaMax allowed its users to pause a recording in order to skip over advertising, but only if they were physically present to press the button.238 However, most BetaMax users actually http://www.intelconsumerelectronics.com/Consumer-Electronics-3.0/TheChanging-TV-Experience.aspx (last visited Oct. 3, 2009) (outlining the various ways in which television users utilize DVR and other television features). 233 This is generally true, although it is conceivable that a company could limit the viewing periods to certain times of certain days. 234 See generally Mike Snider, Old TV Shows Never Die . . . They Grow More Popular on DVD, USA TODAY, Oct. 19, 2004, available at http://www.usatoday.com/life/television/news/2004-10-17-tv-dvds-main_x. htm. 235 Id. 236 Id. 237 This argument is less applicable for radio stations, which are generally not owned by recording companies. However, television companies generally own the television stations on which they play their copyrighted works and therefore earn advertising that is directly correlated with the failure or success of the copyrighted work itself. 238 Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 451 utilized its time-shifting functions when they were not at home, were occupied with other tasks or were viewing another program at the time of broadcast, and therefore they were unable to skip the commercials.239 Although the BetaMax was equipped with a fast forward function that allowed users to skip past commercials, the Court noted that seventy-five percent of BetaMax users chose not to skip the advertisements.240 This likely meant that the targets of the advertising were actually watching it.241 Modern technology has far surpassed the BetaMax.242 Although streaming video on NBC’s website has commercials,243 almost all programs allow for pausing or later editing of the file to remove the commercials.244 This means that even less users will actually see the advertisements, thus circumventing the process by which television broadcast companies “receive” royalties.245 This is essentially the same conduct Napster found to be commercial: a complete circumvention of paying royalties.246 Thus, a court would likely find that a user of a program allowing him or her to download streaming audio or video is a 423 (1984). 239 Id. at 424. 240 Id. at 453 n.36. 241 See id. 242 DVD Players and Recorders not only display movies at a better quality, but they also allow for more content than did BetaMax or VCRs. DVD Demystified, DVD FAQ, http://www.dvddemystified.com/dvdfaq. html#1 (last visited Oct. 25, 2009). 243 See generally NBC Video Library, http://www.nbc.com/Video/ library/ (last visited Oct. 26, 2009) 244 See e.g., Audacity, supra note 66; KeepVid, supra note 66; Orbit Downloader 2.0, supra note 66; WM Capture, supra note 66. 245 The idea is that although the user does not pay directly for broadcast television, he or she does pay for the television show through the imposition of advertising. Vincent, supra note 212, at 13. The less users that watch the show legitimately, the less broadcast companies make. Id. This is because the amount of money a television company can charge an advertiser is based primarily on the popularity of the program. Id. 246 A&M Records, Inc. v. Napster, Inc., 239 F.3d 1004, 1018 (9th Cir. 2000). MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 452 commercial user. Although the user may not be selling his copy for profit, he is still participating in a financially motivated transaction in so far as he can trade his newly recorded show for others through programs that allow end users to share potentially infringing videos with each other. Courts have not hesitated to find that this behavior tips heavily against fair use.247 Factor 2: The Nature of the Copyrighted Work When looking at the nature of use, a court will examine whether the works are creative or factual in nature.248 Those that are inherently more creative are closer to the core of intended copyright protection, and therefore, would likely not be found to be fair use.249 Both audio and video files represent intrinsically creative works and both represent the unique product of a creative mind.250 Thus, a court would find that this factor weighs against a finding of fair use. However, if a user could show that he would have been able to view the show without cost, he or she could tip the balance in favor of fair use, claiming that “the product has not changed[, but] rather[,] downloads of broadcast shows are merely delivered in a different medium.”251 However, it seems illogical that a court would find that just because a user could watch a television show on broadcast television or through a website without paying a premium, downloading the show from a streaming source would favor fair use. Especially because a show is available to stream through the broadcast network’s website for several weeks after it originally airs, but it will rarely be available again until the company releases the DVD of the entire season.252 247 See, e.g., id. at 1015. 17 U.S.C. § 107(2) (2008); see also Napster, 239 F.3d at 1016. 249 Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 510 U.S. 569, 586 (1994). 250 See generally id. 251 Vincent, supra note 212, at 12. 252 See generally ABC, FAQ, http://www.abc.go.com/site/faq (last visited Sept. 7, 2009). 248 MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 453 Factor 3: The Portion Used in Relation to the Whole Similar to commercial use, copying the entirety of a copyrighted work does not preclude a user from claiming fair use, but it certainly weighs heavily in finding against fair use.253 Streaming users typically copy the entirety of the copyrighted work.254 Although time-shifting of movies is one of the rare instances of wholesale copying that is also fair use, courts will draw a distinction between time-shifting using VHS tapes and using personal computers. Such a finding will be influenced by the easy transferability of computer files. Whereas VHS tapes required a purchase and money to share (i.e., postage), computer files can be easily transferred from one computer to another within minutes. A user who downloads a streaming feed therefore retains an entire work for repeated use and easy distribution, thus tipping against a finding of fair use. Factor 4: The Effect of Use Upon the Market Lastly, fair use will only be found when copying the work does not materially impair its marketability.255 Similar to the other factors in the fair use analysis, a finding of market impairment is not dispositive of fair use.256 However, a court will rarely find fair use when the copying impairs the marketability of the original, unless the other three factors weigh very heavily in favor of fair use.257 For a commercial user,258 253 A&M Records, Inc. v. Napster, Inc., 239 F.3d 1004, 1016 (9th Cir. 2000); Worldwide Church of God v. Phila. Church of God, 227 F.3d 1110, 1118 (9th Cir. 2000). 254 See Vincent, supra note 212, at 12. 255 Napster, 239 F.3d at 1016. 256 Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 510 U.S. 569, 590 (1994). 257 See generally id. at 591. 258 Even though I previously concluded that the courts would find users of these programs to be commercial users, for the sake of argument, I will presume that the end user is not considered a commercial user. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 454 market impairment is presumed.259 One commentator has argued that downloading streaming files actually increases the marketability of broadcast television shows.260 Somehow, despite precedent to the contrary,261 some believe that because downloading increases a show’s exposure, a court would be willing to dismiss the act of infringement.262 However, in Napster, the Ninth Circuit explicitly rejected this idea in reference to music downloads.263 The court reasoned that even if all users who downloaded a song on Napster eventually bought the CDs from which they came, fair use would not tip conclusively in favor of a potential infringer.264 Most courts would agree that increased sales should not deprive a copyright holder of the right to license his material.265 A court would not find that users who downloaded and retained files actually contributed to the marketability of the file. Logic dictates that most users are markedly less likely to buy a DVD or watch a streaming, advertisement-laden broadcast over the Internet when they could simply watch the copy they have expertly procured on their computer.266 Furthermore, even if users did eventually erase the files they had taken great pains to obtain, technology, such as writable DVD drives, has made it unnecessary for a user to purchase the official DVD distributed by the copyright owner.267 By writing the files to a DVD, a user 259 See Sony Corp. of Am. v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 464 U.S. 417, 451 (1984). 260 Vincent, supra note 212, at 13. 261 See, e.g., Napster, 239 F.3d at 1016–17. 262 Vincent, supra note 212, at 13. 263 Napster, 239 F.3d at 1018. 264 Id.; see A&M Records, Inc. v. Napster, Inc., 114 F. Supp. 2d 896, 914 (N.D. Cal. 2000), aff’d 239 F.3d 1004, 1018 (9th Cir. 2000). 265 See A&M Records, Inc. v. Napster, Inc., 239 F.3d 1004, 1018 (9th Cir. 2000); Campbell v. Acuff-Rose Music, Inc., 510 U.S. 569, 591 (1994). 266 Studies have shown that people, especially the upper middle class, are very skeptical of advertising. SIDNEY J. LEVY, BRANDS, CONSUMERS, SYMBOLS, & RESEARCH 304 (1999). If people are already skeptical of advertising, putting even more advertising into a streaming television show may make viewing it unpleasant. See generally id. 267 Users are able to buy and use DVD-Recordable Discs to make copies MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 455 can completely circumvent the copyright holder’s legitimate market.268 Further, there is much to consider with respect to a user’s purposeful circumvention of advertisements. Most television viewers and streaming audio and video users view advertising as a nuisance269 and may not be aware of the very specific purpose advertising plays in the availability of broadcast television. Simply put, without advertising, users would be required to pay a subscription fee to see any show.270 Every time a fan of a television show chooses to watch a downloaded version of that program in lieu of watching a rerun or the streaming copy available on the websites of most 271 the broadcast channel is deprived of broadcast channels, 272 advertising revenue. This could have a potentially devastating effect on the market for television shows. Depriving broadcast companies of this revenue could put television shows in danger because advertising companies may be unwilling to advertise of a show. How Do I Burn a DVD?, http://www.tech-faq.com/burn-dvd. shtml (last visited Sept. 7, 2009). Users can download episodes of a television series onto their computer and use this technology to make their own full-season DVD sets that will play on any DVD player. Id. 268 If a user is simply interested in having a portable copy of a television series, a user who has made his or her own full-season DVD has no financial incentive to purchase a DVD released by the copyright holder. Id. 269 Marketing Vox, Our Challenge, http://www.marketingvox.com/our_ challenge_43_say_online_advertising_is_a_nuisance-012302/ (last visited Sept. 7, 2009). Marketing Vox found that in 2003, 53% of Americans found online advertising a nuisance and 65% found television advertising to be a nuisance. Id. 270 Vincent, supra note 212, at 13. 271 NBC, ABC, Fox, and CBS all have a majority of their shows available for streaming on their websites. See NBC, Video Library, http://www.nbc.com/Video/library/ (last visited Sept. 6, 2009); ABC, Shows, http://abc.go.com/watch (last visited Sept. 6, 2009); FOX, On Demand, http://www.fox.com/fod/index.htm?src=menu_item_full_episodes (last visited Sept. 6, 2009); CBS, All Videos, http://www.cbs.com/video/ (last visited Sept. 6, 2009). 272 Liz Gannes, Streaming TV on ABC and MTV is Profitable, NEWTEEVEE, Mar. 18, 2009, http://newteevee.com/2009/03/18/streaming-tvon-abc-and-mtv-is-profitable/. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 456 during shows that are popular among people who watch the show from their personal file.273 Given the huge impact, courts would not find “time-shifting” vis-à-vis downloading streaming audio or video to be a “fair use.” CONCLUSION The world of copyright is continuously changing and Congress—as well as other international legislative bodies— constantly revisits copyright law to accommodate evolving 274 technology and to protect copyright holders from infringement. Copyright holders have a large number of solutions before them to help combat infringement, but with every potential solution a new problem is created. First, television companies could choose not to pursue infringers and to instead recoup lost revenue by reducing the average length of television shows and replace that time with additional advertisements. Similarly, record and movie companies could simply increase the amount of advertising that comes along with streaming audio and video. This, however, could lead to even less patronage and even less revenue, as viewers’ least favorite part about watching television or listening to music would become even more prominent.275 This might be difficult for audio copyright owners, given that they can only insert advertising before or after a song, as a song should not be broken up to accommodate for additional advertising. Alternatively, broadcast companies could increase product placement in television shows to make up for lost revenues. However, television shows with high rates of product placement might be onerous to watch—even for those who view them without commercials—and such nuisance may not do much to 273 How Does Television Advertising Work?, http://www.marketingmine field.co.uk/traditional-marketing/television-advertising/1-overview.html (last visited Oct. 3, 2009). 274 See generally Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Studios, Inc. v. Grokster, Ltd., 545 U.S. 913, 928–29 (2005) (finding it necessary to balance the interests of advancing technology with those of the copyright holder). 275 See supra note 269. MORRIS REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 9:59 PM AUDIO AND VIDEO COPYRIGHT CLAIMS 457 foster legitimate viewership.276 Third, absent zealous prosecution of copyright infringers, copyright holders are forced to constantly modify their encryption technology to stay ahead of software developers looking to exploit their vulnerabilities. This means millions of dollars constantly spent on research and development could be better spent on improving the creative quality of music, television, and movies. The goal of the copyright holder should be to flood the market with widely available free and low cost streaming content in order to prevent users from downloading and infringing on their copyrighted works. This might be difficult to achieve, given that software producers have carefully crafted their programs to avoid liability under the DMCA and to avoid secondary liability under traditional copyright principles.277 Software producers, although generally not charging for their programs, have enough of a financial incentive to continue to make software and actively market and encourage users to use it to infringe on copyrights. However, if the copyright holder can convince the individual user that it is both cost-effective and safe to utilize a myriad of legal alternatives, the copyright holder can shift the user from illegal activity, for which he may be liable, to legal viewing activities in order to protect their copyright from active infringement. 276 277 See supra note 269 and accompanying text. See supra Part III. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS: HOW ANTI-IMMIGRATION SENTIMENT LED TO UNCONSTITUTIONAL LEGISLATION AND THE EROSION OF FUNDAMENTAL PRINCIPLES OF AMERICAN GOVERNMENT Jamie Nielsen* I. INTRODUCTION A. History of the Real ID Act Feeding off of the wave of anti-immigration sentiment following the events of September 11th 2001, the Real ID Act was designed to quell illegal immigration by implementing a national ID card system and bolstering border security. The Act was first introduced by Wisconsin U.S. Representative James Sensenbrenner as part of the Intelligence Reform and Terrorism 1 Prevention Act of 2004. Due to heavy opposition in the Senate, 2 the Real ID provisions were dropped prior to passage. However, it was reintroduced in 2005 and attached to legislation that House leaders were certain would pass in the Senate.3 Thus, * B.S., Bryant University, 2001; J.D., Brooklyn Law School, expected 2010. The author wishes to thank her parents for providing endless support and encouragement, as well as the members of the Journal of Law and Policy for all of their hard work. 1 Intelligence Reform and Terrorism Prevention Act of 2004, Pub. L. No. 108–458, § 7212, 118 Stat. 3638 (2004). 2 Media Matters, O’Reilly Misleadingly Claimed Real ID Act Passed Senate 100-0, MEDIA MATTERS, May 13, 2005, http://mediamatters.org/ items/200505130002. 3 “[A]pparently recognizing that the stand-alone bill lacked support in the Senate, the House leadership attached the legislation to the House version of 459 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 460 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY the bill was passed as a rider to the Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act for Defense, the Global War on Terror, and Tsunami Relief, 2005.4 As noted by one legal scholar, “[i]t would have been a serious political liability for a congressperson to vote against funding for the war on terror and tsunami relief. So it is unsurprising that there was no debate on, no hearings on, and no public vetting of the act.”5 The Real ID Act is most notorious for requiring a national identification card system, which in turn requires states to fund and implement a system of federally standardized drivers licenses.6 The cards will contain the personal information of the holder and will be equipped with machine-readable technology, allowing them to be scanned.7 The cards will not only be necessary for activities such as flying or visiting federal buildings, but also for “‘everyday transactions,’ such as receiving government benefits, voting, or applying for a job. The private sector will also begin mandating a Real ID card for everyday purposes.”8 In order to obtain the new cards, people will be required to present documentation to their state Department of Motor Vehicles proving their “name, date of birth, Social Security number, their principal residence . . . and 9 that they are lawfully in the U.S.” In addition to excluding many individuals living within the states from receiving an ID card,10 the law will be outrageously costly.11 the emergency funding bill.” Id. 4 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act for Defense, the Global War on Terror, and Tsunami Relief, Pub. L. No. 109–13, 119 Stat. 231 (2005). 5 Anita Ramasastry, Why the ‘Real ID’ Act, Which Requires National Identity Cards, is a Real Mess, FINDLAW, Aug. 10, 2005, http://writ.news. findlaw.com/ramasastry/20050810.html. 6 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act §§ 201–207. 7 Id. at § 202(b). 8 New York Civil Liberties Union, Why Oppose the Real ID Act?, http://dev.nyclu.org/realid/why_oppose (last visited Sept. 30, 2009). 9 Ramasastry, supra note 5; see also Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act § 202(c)(1)–(2). 10 The documentation requirements will prevent not only illegal immigrants already residing in the United States from receiving ID cards, but NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 461 While opponents have voiced strong criticism regarding the cost, invasion of privacy, identity theft, and immigrant discrimination that accompany the identification cards,12 little has been said about the other provisions of the Act—in particular Section 102(c)13, designed to amend Section 102(c) of the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act of 1996.14 Section 102 of the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act of 1996 aimed to deter illegal crossings at United States borders with two protective fences “along the 14 miles of the international land border of the United States, starting at the Pacific Ocean and extending eastward.”15 This project was expanded following September 11th, when Congress began to play off of America’s terrorism also many legal immigrants. See NAT’L IMMIGRATION LAW CTR., QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS ABOUT DRIVER’S LICENSES NOW THAT FINAL REAL ID REGULATIONS HAVE BEEN ISSUED (2008), available at http://www.nilc.org/ immspbs/DLs/QA_re_DLs_post-regs_2008-02-27.pdf. Further, legal citizens may have difficulty obtaining the required documents due to factors such as age or poverty. See Joan Fridland, Nat’l Immigration Law Ctr., Presentation at the Immigration Advocates Network Webinar: Immigrants, Driver’s Licenses, and the Real ID Act: Requirements, Implementation, and Options Available to States (Dec. 15, 2006), available at http://www.democracyin action.org/dia/organizationsORG/NILC/images/REAL ID webinar NILC.ppt. 11 The DHS [Department of Homeland Security] originally estimated that the law would cost $23.1 billion. The final regulations slash this estimate to $9.9 billion over 11 years by relying on the ridiculous premise that only 75 percent of licensed drivers will seek to obtain a Real ID. As of February 2008, Congress had set aside only $80 million to help pay for implementing Real ID across the entire country. N.Y. Civil Liberties Union, supra note 8. 12 See, e.g., id.; Real Nightmare, Opposition Voices, http://www.real nightmare.org/opposition/9/ (last visited Sept. 24, 2009). 13 Section 102 of the Real ID Act is titled “Waiver of Legal Requirements Necessary for Improvement of Barriers at Borders.” Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act § 102. 14 8 U.S.C.A. § 1103 note (c) (West 2009) (Improvement of Barriers at Border). 15 Omnibus Consolidated Appropriations Act, Pub. L. No. 104–208, § 102(b)(1), 110 Stat. 3009 (1996). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 462 fears in order to strengthen immigration controls. Amendments such as those made in the Secure Fence Act of 200616 provided for “reinforced fencing along not less than 700 miles of the southwest border.”17 Similarly, while the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act originally provided for waiver of provisions of the Endangered Species Act of 1973 and the National Environmental Policy Act of 1969 “to the extent the Attorney General determines necessary to ensure expeditious construction of the barriers and roads,”18 Section 102(c)(1) of the Real ID Act amended this to read: IN GENERAL.—Notwithstanding any other provision of law, the Secretary of Homeland Security shall have the authority to waive all legal requirements such Secretary, in such Secretary’s sole discretion, determines necessary to ensure expeditious construction of the barriers and roads under this section. Any such decision by the Secretary shall be effective upon being published in the Federal Register.19 The Department of Homeland Security was created as an executive agency by President Bush following September 11th and assumed several functions previously held by other governmental agencies.20 In particular, the authority previously granted to the Attorney General in Section 102 of the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act of 1996 was assigned to the Secretary of Homeland Security.21 Under the new provisions of Section 102 of the Real ID Act, the Secretary 16 Secure Fence Act of 2006, Pub. L. No. 109–367, § 3, 120 Stat. 2638 (2006). 17 8 U.S.C.A. § 1103 note (b)(1)(A) (West 2009) (Improvement of Barriers at Border). 18 Omnibus Consolidated Appropriations Act § 102(c). 19 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act for Defense, the Global War on Terror, and Tsunami Relief, Pub. L. No. 109–13, § 102(c)(1), 119 Stat. 231 (2005). 20 See Homeland Security Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107–296, § 1511, 1517, 116 Stat. 2135 (2002). 21 Id. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 463 now has sole discretion to waive any and all laws he deems necessary for expeditious construction of the border fence, 670 miles of which had a completion deadline of December 31, 2008.22 Additionally, the Real ID Act significantly narrows judicial review of the Secretary’s discretionary decisions: IN GENERAL.—The district courts of the United States shall have exclusive jurisdiction to hear all causes or claims arising from any action undertaken, or any decision made, by the Secretary of Homeland Security pursuant to paragraph (1). A cause of action or claim may only be brought alleging a violation of the Constitution of the United States. The court shall not have jurisdiction to hear any claim not specified in this subparagraph . . . . Any cause or claim brought pursuant to subparagraph (A) shall be filed not less than 60 days after the date of the action or decision made by the Secretary of Homeland Security. A claim shall be barred unless it is filed within the time specified . . . . An interlocutory or final judgment, decree, or order of the district court may be reviewed only upon petition for a writ of certiorari to the Supreme Court of the United States.23 Thus, as this Note will argue, Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act is unconstitutional, violating the separation of powers doctrine by granting entirely too much power to one individual while leaving little room for judicial review. Additionally, when given the opportunity to review the constitutionality of the Act 22 8 U.S.C.A. § 1103 note (b)(1)(B) (West 2009) (Improvement of Barriers at Border). The Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act specified “370 miles, or other mileage determined by the Secretary” shall be completed by December 31, 2008. Id. The Department of Homeland Security committed to having 670 miles of fencing completed by December 31, 2008 (370 miles of pedestrian fencing and 300 miles of vehicle fencing). OFFICE OF THE INSPECTOR GEN., DEP’T OF HOMELAND SEC., OIG09-56, PROGRESS IN ADDRESSING SECURE BORDER INITIATIVE OPERATIONAL REQUIREMENTS AND CONSTRUCTING THE SOUTHWEST BORDER FENCE 15 (2009). 23 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act § 102(c)(2). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 464 in Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff,24 the Supreme Court denied certiorari and failed to perform its job as a check on legislative power. The Note will begin with an overview of Chertoff and the district court’s rationale in upholding the Real ID Act. Part II will examine the historical importance of the separation of powers doctrine, including application of the doctrine in significant case law. Part III will demonstrate the unconstitutionality of the Real ID Act by comparing the Real ID Act to other separation of powers cases. Part IV examines the devastating results of such legislation and the Supreme Court’s inaction. Finally, Part V proposes a solution to redress the consequences of the Court’s inaction. B. Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff In September of 2007, at the direction of the Department of Homeland Security, the Army Corps of Engineers began construction of the border fence, along with a road and drainage structures, in an area known as the San Pedro Riparian National Conservation Area (SPRNCA) in Arizona.25 The SPRNCA consists of approximately 57,000 acres of public land in Cochise County, Arizona.26 The San Pedro River, “one of the last freeflowing rivers in the United States”27 runs though the SPRNCA and the area has been described as “one of the most biologically diverse areas of the United States.”28 Congress officially 24 Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff, 527 F. Supp. 2d 119 (D.D.C. 2007), cert. denied, 128 S. Ct. 2962 (2008). 25 Id. at 121. 26 United States Department of the Interior, San Pedro RNCA, http://blm .gov/az/st/en/prog/blm_special_areas/ncarea/sprnca.html (last visited Sept. 30, 2009) [hereinafter San Pedro RNCA]. 27 Press Release, Defenders of Wildlife & Sierra Club, Conservation Groups Ask Federal Government to Consider Border Fence’s Overall Impact to Wildlife, Public Lands in Arizona (Oct. 1, 2007), available at http://www. defenders.org/newsroom/press_releases_folder/2007/10_01_2007_groups_app eal_to_feds_on_border_fence.php?ht=. 28 Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 121 (internal quotation marks omitted). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 465 designated it as a conservation area on November 18, 1988.29 Recognizing the ecological significance of the SPRNCA and the potential damage of fencing,30 Defenders of Wildlife filed a motion for a temporary restraining order in district court. The motion alleged that the Bureau of Land Management (the agency charged with managing the SPRNCA) conducted an inadequate Environmental Assessment prior to granting a perpetual right of way to the Department of Homeland Security for fence construction31 and that the bureau also erred in determining that an Environmental Impact Statement was not required by the National Environmental Policy Act of 1969.32 Defenders of Wildlife further argued that the right-of-way grant violated the Arizona-Idaho Conservation Act of 1988, which required the Bureau of Land Management to “manage the SPRNCA ‘in a manner that conserves, protects, and enhances the riparian area and the aquatic, wildlife, archeological, paleontological, scientific, cultural, educational, and recreational resources of the 29 San Pedro RNCA, supra note 26. The primary purpose for the special designation is to protect and enhance the desert riparian ecosystem, a rare remnant of what was once an extensive network of similar riparian systems throughout the American Southwest. One of the most important riparian areas in the United States, the San Pedro River runs through the Chihuahuan Desert and the Sonoran Desert in Southeastern Arizona. The river’s stretch is home to 84 species of mammals, 14 species of fish, 41 species of reptiles and amphibians, and 100 species of breeding birds. It also provides invaluable habitat for 250 species of migrant and wintering birds and contains archaeological sites representing the remains of human occupation from 13,000 years ago. Id. 30 Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 121 n.1 (“The challenged fence construction requires excavation on up to 225 of the SPRNCA’s 58,000 acres, and the proposed fence segments will cover approximately 9,938 feet at the border when completed.”). 31 Id. at 121. The Bureau of Land Management “concluded that the proposed fencing would have no significant impact on the environment when paired with certain mitigation measures and that an Environmental Impact Statement (‘IS’) was not therefore required by the National Environmental Policy Act of 1969 (‘NEPA’).” Id. (citations omitted). 32 Id. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 466 conservation area’ and to ‘only allow such uses of the conservation area’ that further the purposes for which it was established.”33 The court granted the temporary restraining order, noting that “plaintiffs had demonstrated a substantial likelihood of success on the merits with respect to their NEPA claims and that the balance of equities favored plaintiffs,”34 and construction of the border fence was halted.35 However, approximately two weeks later, the Secretary of Homeland Security, Michael Chertoff, used his discretionary powers to waive twenty statutes in their entirety (most of them environmental) in order to continue the fence construction.36 33 Id. Id. 35 Id. 36 On October 26, 2007, the Secretary’s decision to waive the following statutes was announced in the Federal Register: The National Environmental Policy Act (Pub. L. 91–190, 83 Stat. 852 (Jan. 1, 1970) (42 U.S.C. 4321 et seq.)), the Endangered Species Act (Pub. L. 93–205, 87 Stat. 884 (Dec. 28, 1973) (16 U.S.C. 1531 et seq.)), the Federal Water Pollution Control Act (commonly referred to as the Clean Water Act) (Act of June 30, 1948, c. 758, 62 Stat. 1155 (33 U.S.C. 1251 et seq.)), the National Historic Preservation Act (Pub. L. 89–665, 80 Stat. 915 (Oct. 15, 1966) (16 U.S.C. 470 et seq.)), the Migratory Bird Treaty Act (16 U.S.C. 703 et seq.), the Clean Air Act (42 U.S.C. 7401 et seq.), the Archeological Resources Protection Act (Pub. L. 96–95, 16 U.S.C. 470aa et seq.), the Safe Drinking Water Act (42 U.S.C. 300f et seq.), the Noise Control Act (42 U.S.C. 4901 et seq.), the Solid Waste Disposal Act, as amended by the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act (42 U.S.C. 6901 et seq.), the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act (42 U.S.C. 9601 et seq.), the Federal Land Policy and Management Act (Pub. L. 94–579, 43 U.S.C. 1701 et seq.), the Fish and Wildlife Coordination Act (Pub. L. 73– 121, 48 Stat. 401, 16 U.S.C. 661 et seq.), the Archaeological and Historic Preservation Act (Pub. L. 86–523, 16 U.S.C. 469 et seq.), the Antiquities Act (16 U.S.C. 431 et seq.), the Historic Sites, Buildings, and Antiquities Act (16 U.S.C. 461 et seq.), the Arizona-Idaho Conservation Act of 1988 (Pub. L. 100–696, 16 U.S.C. 460xx et seq.), the Wild and Scenic Rivers Act (Pub. L. 90–542, 16 U.S.C. 1281 et seq.), the Farmland Protection Policy Act (7 U.S.C. 4201 et seq.) and the Administrative Procedure Act (5 U.S.C. 551 et seq.). Determination Pursuant to Section 102 of the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act of 1996 as Amended by Section 102 of the REAL ID Act of 2005 and as Amended by the Secure 34 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 467 Additionally, Chertoff stated that he reserved the “authority to make further waivers from time to time.”37 Using the highly subjective standards set forth in the Act, Chertoff stated that the SPRNCA “is an area of high illegal entry” in which “there is presently a need to erect fixed and mobile barriers . . . and roads.”38 Therefore, he deemed it “necessary” to exercise his waiver authority and, as a result, the temporary restraining order was vacated.39 In response, Defenders of Wildlife filed an amended complaint in district court, alleging “that the waiver provision of the REAL ID Act violates separation of powers principles embodied in Articles I and II of the Constitution because it ‘impermissibly delegates legislative powers to the DHS Secretary, a politically-appointed Executive Branch official.”40 Specifically, the plaintiffs argued that the case fell precisely within the Court’s holding in Clinton v. City of New York,41 where provisions of the Line Item Veto Act were found unconstitutional because Presidential repeal of laws is not constitutionally permissible.42 The defendants moved to dismiss the complaint43 on grounds that the Real ID Act’s waiver provisions constituted a permissible delegation of legislative power to the Executive Branch under the Court’s “nondelegation” jurisprudence because “it provides the Secretary with an ‘intelligible principle’ that ‘clearly delineate[s] the general policy, the public agency which is to apply it, and the boundaries of th[e] delegated authority.’”44 Additionally, the defendants set forth the argument that “‘Congress may delegate in even broader terms’ than otherwise permissible in matters of Fence Act of 206, 72 Fed. Reg. 60,870 (Oct. 26, 2007). 37 Id. 38 Id. 39 Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 123. 40 Id. 41 Id. at 124 (citing Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417 (1998)). 42 Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417, 438 (1998). 43 Defendants moved to dismiss under FED. R. CIV. P. 12(b)(1) and 12(b)(6). Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 123. 44 Id. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 468 immigration policy, foreign affairs, and national security, because ‘the Executive Branch already maintains significant independent control’ over these areas.”45 In issuing its opinion, the district court quickly dismissed the plaintiff’s comparison to Clinton.46 The court held that the repeal of laws in Clinton was distinguishable from the waiver of laws at issue here.47 Whereas in Clinton repeal meant the affected laws no longer had “any ‘legal force or effect’ under any circumstance,”48 the waived laws at issue “retain[] the same legal force and effect [they] had when [] passed by both houses of Congress and presented to the President.”49 The court further stated: The fact that the laws no longer apply to the extent they otherwise would have with respect to the construction of border barriers and roads within the SPRNCA does not, as plaintiffs argue, transform the waiver into an unconstitutional ‘partial repeal’ of those laws. By that logic, any waiver, no matter how limited in scope, would violate Article I because it would allow the Executive Branch to unilaterally ‘repeal’ or nullify the law with respect to the limited purpose delineated by the waiver legislation.50 With regard to the plaintiffs’ separation of powers argument, the court cited the rationale from Smith v. Fed. Reserve Bank of N.Y. that “‘the Supreme Court has widely permitted the Congress to delegate its legislative authority to other branches,’ so long as the delegation is accompanied by sufficient guidance.”51 Further, that delegation is permitted where “Congress ‘lay[s] down . . . an intelligible principle to which 45 Id. Id. at 124. 47 Id. 48 Id. 49 Id. 50 Id. 51 Id. at 126 (citing Smith v. Fed. Reserve Bank of N.Y., 280 F. Supp. 2d 314, 324 (S.D.N.Y. 2003)). 46 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 469 the person or body authorized to [exercise the delegated authority] is directed to conform . . . .’”52 The Chertoff court held that the provisions requiring that fencing be erected specifically in areas “of high illegal entry,”53 “to deter illegal crossings,”54 and that the Secretary only exercise his waiver authority as he “determines necessary to ensure expeditious construction of the barriers and roads”55 constituted “clearly delineated” boundaries under which the Secretary was authorized to act.56 The Chertoff court also found that the broad scope of the Secretary’s power to waive “all legal requirements”57 that he deems necessary in his “sole discretion”58 was not 59 Despite finding a lack of historical support unconstitutional. for such sweeping waiver authority,60 the court found that it was constitutional because “under the nondelegation doctrine, the relevant inquiry is whether the Legislative Branch has laid down an intelligible principle to guide the Executive Branch, not the scope of the waiver power.”61 The court further agreed with the 62 defendants that legislative delegations may be broader when the subject matter is one over which the Executive Branch already 52 Id. at 127 (citing Mistretta v. United States, 488 U.S. 361, 372 (1989)). 53 8 U.S.C.A. § 1103 note (a) (West 2009) (Improvement of Barriers at Border). 54 Id. 55 Id. note (c)(1). 56 Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 127. 57 8 U.S.C.A. § 1103 note (c)(1) (West 2009) (Improvement of Barriers at Border). 58 Id. 59 Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 129. 60 The Court cited a Congressional Research Service Memorandum which stated “the REAL ID Act’s waiver provision appears to be unprecedented in that it ‘contains notwithstanding language,’ provides a secretary of an executive agency the authority to waive all laws such secretary determines necessary, and directs the secretary to waive such laws.” Id. at 128. 61 Id. at 129. 62 See supra text accompanying note 45. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 470 possesses considerable constitutional power.63 Therefore, because the border fence falls under the Executive controlled areas of foreign affairs and immigration control,64 the broad delegation of authority to the Secretary of Homeland Security by the legislature was constitutionally permissible.65 Following the district court’s dismissal with prejudice, Defenders of Wildlife exercised the only available option under the Act and petitioned for a writ of certiorari to the Supreme Court.66 Fourteen members of the U.S. House of Representatives, numerous distinguished law professors, and various organizations (ranging from environmental groups to the United Church of Christ) filed Amicus briefs in support of the 67 petitioners. However, in June of 2008, the Supreme Court denied certiorari.68 In a public statement, House Representative Lamar Smith criticized the Supreme Court’s decision as allowing border fences to be built “without legal restrictions or interference from environmentalists.”69 Rule 10 of the Rules of the Supreme Court of the United States sets forth basic guidelines for the Court to grant a petition 63 “When the area to which the legislation pertains is one where the Executive Branch already has significant independent constitutional authority, delegations may be broader than in other contexts.” Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 129 (citing Sierra Club v. Ashcroft, Civ. No. 04–272, 2005 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 44244, at *17 (S.D. Cal. Dec. 12, 2005)). 64 Id. at 129. 65 Id. 66 Petition for Writ of Certiorari, Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff, 128 S. Ct. 2962 (2008) (No. 07-1180). 67 Brief for Fourteen Members of the U.S. House of Representatives as Amici Curiae in Support of Petitioners, Defenders of Wildlife, 128 S. Ct. 2962 (No. 07–1180); Brief of William D. Araiza et al. as Amici Curiae in Support of Petitioners, Defenders of Wildlife, 128 S. Ct. 2962 (No. 07– 1180); Brief of the National Advocacy Center of the Sisters of the Good Shepherd et al. as Amici Curiae Support of Petitioners, Defenders of Wildlife, 128 S. Ct. 2962 (No. 07–1180). 68 Defenders of Wildlife, 128 S. Ct. 2962. 69 Gary Martin, Court’s Fence Ruling Strengthens Government Power, SAN ANTONIO EXPRESS-NEWS, June 28, 2008, at 9B. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 471 for certiorari.70 Of those standards, one is particularly pertinent—where “a state court or a United States court of appeals has decided an important question of federal law that has not been, but should be, settled by this Court, or has decided an important federal question in a way that conflicts with relevant decisions of this Court” the court should grant certiorari.71 The Court’s denial of certiorari without explanation has left commentators at a loss, with some speculating that “the decision served as a death knell for future legal challenges to the fence,”72 and others holding out “hope that a second, separate legal challenge may yet succeed.”73 Nevertheless, it is clear that the Court should have granted certiorari because the district court’s decision to uphold Section 102(c) of the Act “conflicts with relevant decisions of”74 the Supreme Court by violating the fundamental doctrine of separation of powers. II. SEPARATION OF POWERS AND CHECKS AND BALANCES A. Historical Significance of Separation of Powers The Constitution clearly divides the power of the federal government into three distinct branches, with Article I granting legislative power to Congress,75 Article II giving executive power to the President,76 and Article III vesting judicial power in 77 the Supreme Court. In The Federalist No. 47, James Madison 70 SUP. CT. R. 10. Id. at 10(c). 72 Martin, supra note 69. 73 Border Fence Legal Waivers Still Under Threat in Second Lawsuit, DEF. ENV’T ALERT, Jul. 8, 2008. 74 SUP. CT. R. 10(c). 75 “All legislative Powers herein granted shall be vested in a Congress of the United States which shall consist of a Senate and a House of Representatives.” U.S. CONST. art. I, § 1. 76 “The executive Power shall be vested in a President of the United States of America. U.S. CONST. art. II, § 1, cl. 1. 77 “The judicial Power of the United States, shall be vested in one supreme Court, and in such inferior Courts as the Congress may from time to time ordain and establish.” U.S. CONST. art. III, § 1. 71 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 472 wrote that “the accumulation of all powers, legislative, executive, and judiciary, in the same hands, whether of one, a few, or many, and whether hereditary, self-appointed, or elective, may justly be pronounced the very definition of tyranny.”78 Thus, the founding fathers recognized that in order to maintain this democratic form of government, a reliable method of reigning in branch power was essential.79 Thus, the constitutional system of checks and balances was created, whereby “the President . . . may veto legislation; the Senate may confirm or deny the President’s appointment of his or her principal executive officers as well as federal judges; and Congress, by exercising its impeachment power, may remove judges and executive officers, including the President.”80 In addition to these explicit grants of authority, the power of judicial review stands as one of the most important constitutionally implied checks.81 Chief Justice Marshall categorically reinforced this principal in Marbury v. Madison,82 holding that “it is emphatically the province and duty of the judicial department to say what the law is.”83 78 THE FEDERALIST NO. 47, at 313 (James Madison) (Sherman F. Mittell, ed., 1938). 79 But the great security against a gradual concentration of the several powers in the same department, consists in giving to those who administer each department the necessary constitutional means and personal motives to resist encroachment of the others . . . . Ambition must be made to counteract ambition . . . . If men were angels, no government would be necessary. If angels were to govern men, neither external nor internal controls on government would be necessary. In framing a government which is to be administered by men over men, the great difficulty lies in this: you must first enable the government to control the governed; and in the next place oblige it to control itself. THE FEDERALIST NO. 51, at 337 (James Madison) (Sherman F. Mittell, ed., 1938). 80 CALVIN MASSEY, AMERICAN CONSTITUTIONAL LAW 333 (2d ed. 2005). 81 Id. 82 Marbury v. Madison, 5 U.S. 137 (1803). 83 Id. at 177. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 473 The separation of powers doctrine, and its accompanying system of checks and balances, is a fundamental characteristic of the American government. As stated by Professor Thomas Sargentich, the doctrine continues to “serve the highly valued ends of avoiding undue concentration of governmental power, expanding representation and access to power, as well as promoting deliberation and counteracting factional influence on the government.”84 In Sargentich’s analysis of the separation of powers, the “normally emphasized”85 function of “prevention of concentrated power”86 is only part of the greater purpose served; the doctrine also brings together different actors in an effort to develop public policy. Legislation must filter through three distinct arenas before impacting society.87 Thus, public policy evolves from a broad base, more representative of the needs and values of American citizens.88 The separation of powers doctrine “also multiplies the points of access for citizens who wish to get involved . . . [and] expands access to power in a society with great diversity and 89 Complementing this principle of social division.” comprehensive representation is Sargentich’s point that the doctrine encourages discourse on varying societal attitudes.90 By forcing the branches to deliberate, differing viewpoints are expressed and compromises are inevitably made, thus 84 Thomas O. Sargentich, The Contemporary Assault on Checks and Balances, 7 WIDENER J. PUB. L. 231, 240 (1998). 85 Id. at 236. 86 Id. at 237. 87 The second value served by the separation of powers and checks and balances is to bring together three main governmental actors in the development of public policy: the House of Representatives, elected from local districts; the Senate, elected from the states; and the President, elected in a national electoral contest. Id. at 239. 88 See id. 89 Id. 90 “[T]he separation of powers and checks and balances tend to promote deliberation about public values and public purposes.” Id. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 474 minimizing the possible influence of special interest groups.91 It would be impossible and, perhaps, counterproductive to draw a clean line between each branch of government. The separation of powers doctrine “did not mean that these departments ought to have no partial agency in, or no control over, the acts of each other.”92 Therefore, the Supreme Court has consistently solidified the importance of the separation of powers doctrine and the necessity of judicial review, while recognizing the need for some interaction among the branches. B. Application of the Doctrine in Case Law In J.W. Hampton, Jr., & Co. v. United States93 the Court set forth the enduring rule governing when Congress may tip the delicate balance between the three separate powers and delegate its authority.94 While reaffirming that “Congress may not delegate its purely legislative power to a commission,”95 the Court held that legislative delegation is permissible when Congress has set forth an “intelligible principle”96 to which the authorized party must adhere.97 Years later, in Mistretta v. United States,98 the Court reaffirmed Congress’s constitutional power to delegate its authority in certain situations. Recognizing that “in our increasingly complex society, replete with ever changing and more technical problems, Congress simply cannot do its job absent an ability to delegate power under general 91 See id. at 239–40. “The key idea is that the requirement of having each of the named constitutional actors agree on a new statutory standard makes it harder for a [special interest group] to capture the government.” Id. at 240. 92 THE FEDERALIST NO. 47 (James Madison), supra note 78, at 314 (emphasis in original). 93 J.W. Hampton, Jr., & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 394 (1928) (upholding congressional delegation of power to the President to increase or decrease duties according to the Tariff Act of 1922). 94 Id. at 409. 95 Id. at 408. 96 Id. at 409. 97 Id. 98 Mistretta v. United States, 488 U.S. 361 (1989). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 475 directives,”99 the Court permitted Congress to delegate drafting of the federal sentencing guidelines to the United States Sentencing Commission,100 an independent agency under the judicial branch of the government.101 Reaffirming the “intelligible principal”102 doctrine, the Mistretta Court held that “Congress’ delegation of authority to the Sentencing Commission [was] sufficiently specific and detailed to meet constitutional requirements.”103 While upholding congressional delegations that are sufficiently narrow and precise enough not to violate the separation of powers, the Supreme Court has diligently protected the doctrine and struck down legislation that strays beyond these specifications, or grants too much power to one branch.104 In recent years, the Court has exercised its power of judicial review in several cases involving legislation bearing a marked resemblance to Section 102(c) of the Act.105 For example, in INS v. Chadha,106 the Court declared a legislative provision unconstitutional for violating the separation of powers.107 At issue in Chadha was Section 244(c)(2) of the Immigration and Nationality Act,108 which allowed either House of Congress to veto, or invalidate, a decision by the Executive Branch to 99 Id. at 372. Id. at 374 (upholding Sentencing Reform Act of 1984, Pub. L. No. 98-473, 98 Stat. 1837 (1987) (codified as amended in 18 U.S.C. § 3551 et seq. (1988) and 28 U.S.C. §§ 991–98 (1988))). 101 An Overview of the United States Sentencing Commission, http://www.ussc.gov/general/USSC_Overview_200906.pdf (last visited November 14, 2009). 102 J.W. Hampton, 276 U.S. at 409. 103 Mistretta, 488 U.S. at 374. 104 See, e.g., Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417 (1998); Immigration & Naturalization Serv. v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919 (1983). 105 See, e.g., Chadha, 462 U.S. 919 (holding a congressional veto provision of the Immigration and Nationality Act unconstitutional). 106 Id. 107 Id. at 959. 108 Immigration and Nationality Act § 244(c)(2), 8 U.S.C. 1254(c)(2) (repealed by the Omnibus Consolidated Appropriations Act, Pub. L. No. 104-208, § 308(b)(7), 110 Stat. 3009-615 (1996)). 100 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 476 suspend deportation of an alien residing in the United States.109 The Court began by noting that “[the] principle of separation of powers was not simply an abstract generalization in the minds of the Framers: it was woven into the document that they drafted in Philadelphia in the summer of 1787.”110 In analyzing the provision, the Court held that the House action authorized under Section 244(c)(2) was essentially legislative action, requiring conformance with constitutionally established procedures.111 Therefore, the Court held the “congressional veto provision in § 244 (c)(2) . . . unconstitutional.”112 The Court felt that the provision granted too much power to one House of Congress113 and again emphasized the importance of maintaining the specific constitutional powers of each branch: The bicameral requirement, the Presentment Clauses, the President’s veto, and Congress’ power to override a veto were intended to erect enduring checks on each Branch and to protect the people from the improvident exercise of power by mandating certain prescribed steps. To preserve those checks, and maintain the separation of 109 Id. The Immigration and Nationality Act contained a valid congressional delegation of Executive Power to the Attorney General. Id. § 244(a)(1). The delegation set forth an intelligible principle under which the Attorney General was authorized to suspend the deportation of an alien provided that said alien met explicit requirements of the Act, specifically, a continuous physical presence in the United States during the immediately preceding seven years, good moral character, and extreme hardship to the alien or a family member (a United States citizen or lawful permanent resident) upon deportation. Id. 110 Chadha, 462 U.S. at 946 (citing Buckley v. Valeo, 424 U.S. 1, 124 (1976)). 111 The single House action authorized under Section 244(c)(2) did not fall under any of the four constitutional exceptions allowing one House of Congress to act alone. Id. at 955. 112 Id. at 959. 113 See id. In his concurrence, Justice Powell argued that such cases, involving legislative veto provisions, should be decided on a narrower basis, but nonetheless agreed with the outcome. Justice Powell stated, “when Congress finds that a particular person does not satisfy the statutory criteria for permanent residence in this country it has assumed a judicial function in violation of the separation of powers.” Id. at 960 (Powell, J., concurring). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 477 powers, the carefully defined limits on the power of each Branch must not be eroded.114 Further evidence of the Court’s customary protection of the doctrine can be found in the more recent case Clinton v. City of New York.115 Despite the district court’s contrary holding in Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff,116 the legislation struck down in Clinton is strikingly similar to Section 102(c) of the Act.117 In the well-known Clinton case, the Court held as unconstitutional the Line Item Veto Act of 1996118 which gave the President the power to cancel, or veto, any provision of a bill signed into law that fell under one of three specified categories.119 The Court, reaffirming Chadha, held that “[r]epeal of statutes, no less than enactment, must conform with Art. I,”120 and noted that “[t]here is no provision in the Constitution that authorizes the President to enact, amend, or repeal statutes.”121 Presidential veto power is authorized only before a bill becomes law and, even then, it may be “overridden by a two-thirds vote in each House.”122 The Court further clarified the difference between a permissible Presidential veto and unconstitutional repeal: There are important differences between the President’s “return” of a bill pursuant to Article I, § 7, and the 114 115 116 Id. at 957–58 (majority opinion). Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417 (1998). Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff, 527 F. Supp. 2d 119, 129 (D.D.C. 2007). 117 See Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417 (1998). Line Item Veto Act of 1996 § 204, 2 U.S.C.S. § 691 (2008), invalidated by Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417 (1998). 119 The Line Item Veto Act provided for presidential cancellation of any provision consisting of “(1) any dollar amount of discretionary budget authority; (2) any item of new direct spending; or (3) any limited tax benefit,” provided that the cancellation would “(i) reduce the Federal budget deficit; (ii) not impair any essential Government functions; and (iii) not harm he national interest” and that the President adhere to explicit guidelines in considering the cancellation. Id. 120 Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417, 438 (1998) (citing Immigration & Naturalization Serv. v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919, 954 (1983)). 121 Id. 122 Id. 118 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 478 exercise of the President’s cancellation authority pursuant to the Line Item Veto Act. The constitutional return takes place before the bill becomes law; the statutory cancellation occurs after the bill becomes law. The constitutional return is of the entire bill; the statutory cancellation is of only a part. Although the Constitution expressly authorizes the President to play a role in the process of enacting statutes, it is silent on the subject of unilateral Presidential action that either repeals or amends parts of duly enacted statutes.123 The Court interpreted this silence as “equivalent to an express prohibition.”124 Because the Framers went to such lengths to specify the procedures necessary for statutory enactment, the Court found that the omission of any language authorizing post-enactment repeal prohibits such action.125 Thus, the Court held that the end result of legislation affected by the Line Item Veto Act would not be “the product of the ‘finely wrought procedure’ the Framers designed.”126 Justice Kennedy clearly articulated the non-delegation principle, asserting that “[b]y increasing the power of the President beyond what the Framers envisioned, the statute compromises the political liberty of our citizens, liberty which the separation of powers seeks to secure.”127 Notably, Kennedy’s statement also describes Section 102(c) of the Act, which has not been struck down and is still in force today. III. UNCONSTITUTIONALITY OF SECTION 102(C) OF THE REAL ID ACT A. Comparison to Clinton v. City of New York Similar to the Line Item Veto Act, Section 102(c) of the 123 124 125 126 127 Id. at 438–39. Id. at 439. See id. Id. at 440. Id. at 452 (Kennedy, J., concurring). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 479 Real ID Act vests too much power in one individual. Moreover, because the power is vested in the secretary of an administrative agency, a politically appointed position, the statute represents an especially drastic deviation from the Framers’ vision.128 Further, the power granted to the President under the Line Item Veto Act was subject to more restrictions than that granted to the Secretary of the Department of Homeland Security under Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act. While the Line Item Veto Act set forth specific requirements for the provisions subject to cancellation,129 it also provided for a built in check on the President’s cancellation power.130 By contrast, the Real ID Act provides no specific requirements for the waiver of laws; the Secretary is granted “authority to waive all legal requirements such Secretary, in such Secretary’s sole discretion, determines necessary to ensure expeditious construction of the barriers and roads.”131 There is no built in check on the Secretary’s power. The Secretary’s waiver decision can only be examined through judicial review;132 therefore, unless a party with standing files suit, the decision will go unchecked. Significantly, even if a party with standing seeks judicial review, the narrow requirements for such a suit make it highly unlikely to 128 See supra note 79. See supra note 119. 130 A cancellation takes effect upon receipt by Congress of the special message from the President. If, however, a “disapproval bill” pertaining to a special message is enacted into law, the cancellations set forth in that message become “null and void.” The Act sets forth a detailed expedited procedure for the consideration of a “disapproval bill” . . . . A majority vote of both Houses is sufficient to enact a disapproval bill. The Act does not grant the President the authority to cancel a disapproval bill, but he does, of course, retain constitutional authority to veto such a bill. Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417, 436–37 (1998) (citing 2 U.S.C.S. § 691). 131 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act for Defense, the Global War on Terror, and Tsunami Relief, Pub. L. No. 109-13, § 102(c)(1), 119 Stat. 231 (2005). 132 See supra text accompanying note 23. 129 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 480 succeed.133 Though the separation of powers violations in the Real ID Act are more flagrant than those embodied in the Line Item Veto Act, the two statutes, nevertheless, bear remarkable similarities. The Court in Clinton explicitly stated that “[t]he cancellation of one section of a statute may be the functional equivalent of a partial repeal even if a portion of the section is not cancelled.”134 In Clinton, a partial repeal was held unconstitutional under Article I, Section 7.135 A “partial repeal” is precisely what the Secretary of Homeland Security is authorized to do under the Real ID Act.136 By refusing to apply any and all statutes he deems necessary along the border, the Secretary is in effect partially repealing these statutes.137 While the district court held that this did not constitute a partial repeal because a waived law “retains the same legal force and effect as it had when it was passed by both houses of Congress and presented to the President,”138 this is clearly not the case. When statutes, particularly environmental ones, are enacted they are intended to protect specific places or things deemed especially valuable to society and to ensure the safety and health of citizens.139 How can it logically be argued that these statutes are not being partially repealed when they exempt over 700 miles of United States land,140 containing various endangered species141 and 133 See id. Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417, 441 (1998). 135 Id. at 444. 136 Plaintiff’s Opposition to Defendants’ Renewed Motion to Dismiss, Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff, 527 F. Supp. 2d 119 (D.D.C. 2007) (No. 07-1801); Plaintiff’s Lodged Surreply to Defendants’ Renewed Motion to Dismiss, Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d 119 (No. 07-1801). 137 Plaintiff’s Opposition to Defendants’ Renewed Motion, supra note 136; Plaintiff’s Lodged Surreply, supra note 136. 138 Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 124. 139 See supra note 36. 140 8 U.S.C.A. § 1103 note (b)(1)(A) (West 2009) (Improvement of Barriers at Border). 141 Defenders of Wildlife, Border Fence Construction: San Pedro Riparian NCA, http://www.defenders.org/programs_and_policy/in_the_ courts/legal_docket/border_fence_construction_san_pedro_riparian_nca.php 134 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 481 specifically designated as a conservation area?142 When statutes are not applied to several of the items they were designed to protect, they are being partially repealed. While the district court stated that labeling the Secretary’s actions under the Real ID Act a partial repeal would invalidate “numerous other statutory authorizations of executive waivers,”143 this reasoning is flawed. The statutory waiver authorizations cited by the district court in support of this proposition were far more specific and detailed than the sweeping authorization in Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act.144 Further, the Line Item Veto Act “require[d] the President to adhere to precise procedures whenever he exercises his cancellation authority. In identifying items for cancellation he must consider the legislative history, the purposes, and other relevant information about the items,”145 while the Real ID Act requires no such consideration and is entirely discretionary on (last visited Sept. 30, 2009). 142 See supra note 29. 143 Defenders of Wildlife, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 125. 144 The court cited: 10 U.S.C. § 433 (Secretary of Defense, “in connection with a commercial activity,” may waive compliance with “certain Federal laws or regulations pertaining to the management and administration of Federal agencies” if they would “create an unacceptable risk of compromise of an authorized intelligence activity”); 15 U.S.C. § 2621 (EPA may waive compliance with Toxic Substances Act “upon a request and determination by the President that the requested waiver is necessary in the interest of national defense.”); 20 U.S.C. § 7426(e) (Secretaries of the Interior, Labor, Health and Human Services, and Education “[n]otwithstanding any other provision of law. . . shall have the authority to waive any regulation, policy, or procedure promulgated by [their] department” necessary for the integration of education and related services provided to Indian students); 22 U.S.C. § 7207(a)(3) (President may waive a statutory prohibition on assistance to certain countries “to the degree [he] determines that it is in the national security interest of the United States to do so, or for humanitarian reasons”). Id. at 125 n.5. 145 Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417, 436 (1998). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 482 the part of the Secretary.146 This raises the obvious question of why there is such incongruence between the Supreme Court’s management of the two Acts. After declaring the Line Item Veto Act unconstitutional, the Court declined to test the constitutionality of the Real ID Act,147 thereby permitting a violation of the separation of powers. B. Comparison to INS v. Chadha Similar inconsistency can be seen when comparing the Court’s inaction in Defenders of Wildlife to its holding in Immigration and Naturalization Service v. Chadha.148 The legislative veto at issue in Chadha was, as the Court conceded, a “convenient shortcut.”149 However, while acknowledging that a one House veto was “on its face, an appealing compromise,” the Court stated that “it is crystal clear from the records of the Convention, contemporaneous writings and debates, that the Framers ranked other values higher than efficiency.”150 Allowing the Secretary of the Department of Homeland Security to waive “all legal requirements . . . [he] determines necessary to ensure expeditious construction”151 of border fences and roads clearly has the appeal of swift action. During the period of increasing xenophobia following September 11th, the rapid completion of border reinforcements became desirable to many government 152 officials and American citizens alike. However, as the Court 146 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act for Defense, the Global War on Terror, and Tsunami Relief, Pub. L. No. 109–13, § 102(c)(1), 119 Stat. 231 (2005). 147 Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff, 128 S. Ct. 2962 (2008). 148 Immigration & Naturalization Serv. v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919 (1983) (holding one-House veto provision of the Immigration and Nationality Act unconstitutional). 149 Id. at 958. 150 Id. at 958–59. 151 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act § 102(c)(1). 152 See Jeffrey M. Jones, Nearly Half of Americans Say Immigration Levels Should Be Decreased, GALLUP, July 10, 2003, http://www.gallup. com/poll/8815/Nearly-Half-Americans-Say-Immigration-Levels-ShouldDecreased.aspx. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 483 noted in Chadha, “[t]he choices we discern as having been made in the Constitutional Convention impose burdens on governmental processes that often seem clumsy, inefficient, even unworkable, but those hard choices were consciously made by men who had lived under a form of government that permitted arbitrary governmental acts to go unchecked.”153 Of course it is a convenient shortcut to waive any and all statutes that would interfere with border reinforcements, most of which are environmental and would require surveys and the possible alteration of construction plans. However, the separation of powers doctrine forbids such an unrestrained grant of power to one individual and, as the Court stated in Chadha, “[t]here is no support in the Constitution or decisions of this Court for the proposition that the cumbersomeness and delays often encountered in complying with explicit constitutional standards may be avoided, either by Congress or by the President.”154 Simply put, no branch of government may discount the carefully constructed constitutional system of separation of powers and checks and balances in the interest of efficiency. This tension between expediency and constitutionality is not the only parallel between Section 244(c)(1) of the Immigration and Nationality Act and Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act.155 Both acts deal with the power to nullify constitutionally valid decisions or statutes.156 Clearly, the doctrine of checks and balances places great emphasis on the value of internal government regulation.157 However, this process was carefully laid out in the Constitution and the power to nullify proposed 158 legislation was delegated to the President. This delegation of power “was based on the profound conviction of the Framers that the powers conferred on Congress were the powers to be 153 Chadha, 462 U.S. at 959. Id. (referencing Youngstown Sheet & Tube Co. v. Sawyer, 343 U.S. 579 (1952)). 155 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act § 102(c)(2). 156 See supra text accompanying notes 19, 109. 157 See supra note 79. 158 U.S. CONST. art. I, § 7, cl. 2. 154 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 484 most carefully circumscribed.”159 Because no such veto power was conferred elsewhere, the Court in Chadha held that the ability of one House of Congress to void a constitutionally valid decision of the Executive Branch was unconstitutional.160 Similarly, the ability of one Executive Branch administrative agency officer to waive any and all statutes he deems necessary far exceeds the Framers’ precisely carved out veto provision.161 The current system is far from perfect, but as the Court aptly stated in Chadha, “[w]ith all the obvious flaws of delay, untidiness, and potential for abuse, we have not yet found a better way to preserve freedom than by making the exercise of power subject to the carefully crafted restraints spelled out in the Constitution.”162 It is when these explicit constitutional procedures begin to erode in the name of convenience that the entire system of government is in danger. While there exists a natural push and pull between the three branches, it is expected that when legislation extends beyond constitutional boundaries, the Court will step in and perform its function as a legislative check.163 These decisions will not always be straightforward. As the Court stated in Chadha, “[q]uestions may occur which we would gladly avoid; but we cannot avoid them. All we can do is, to exercise our best judgment, and conscientiously to perform our duty.”164 However, instead of performing its constitutionally appointed duty, the Court chose to avoid the issue in Defenders of Wildlife. Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act should have been evaluated by the Court and declared unconstitutional for violating the separation of powers doctrine, specifically its nondelegation doctrine. 159 Immigration & Naturalization Serv. v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919, 947 (1983). 160 161 162 163 164 Id. at 959. See U.S. CONST. art. I, § 7, cl. 2. Chadha, 462 U.S. at 959. See supra notes 77–79 and accompanying text. Chadha, 462 U.S. at 944. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 485 C. The Intelligible Principle Requirement of the Nondelegation Doctrine Recognizing that, in an ever-changing, complicated society, circumstances would necessarily arise in which congressional delegation of authority was warranted, the Supreme Court set forth strict guidelines for such delegation in J.W. Hampton Jr., & Co. v. United States.165 Under the nondelegation doctrine, Congress may enact legislation delegating some of its rulemaking authority to administrative agencies as long as the legislation sets forth an “intelligible principle” to which the agency must adhere.166 Because Congress had provided explicit 167 guidelines in the Tariff Act of 1922, its delegation of tariff adjustment duties to the President was held constitutional in Hampton.168 Specifically, the President was only permitted to 169 adjust tariffs when certain requirements were met. Congress also provided a detailed list of factors for the President to consider in making his determination.170 Investigations were 165 J.W. Hampton, Jr., & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 394 (1928). Id. at 409. 167 Tariff Act of Sept. 21, 1922, ch. 356, § 315, 42 Stat. 941–943 (repealed 1930). 168 J.W. Hampton, 276 U.S. 394. 169 When the difference between the domestic production cost of a product and the production cost of the product in a competing foreign country was not equalized by the current tariff, the President was authorized to adjust the tariff in order to achieve equalization. Id. at 401. 170 (c). That in ascertaining the differences in costs of production, under the provisions of subdivisions (a) and (b) of this section, the President, in so far as he finds it practicable, shall take into consideration (1) the differences in conditions in production, including wages, costs of material, and other items in costs of production of such or similar articles in the United States and in competing foreign countries; (2) the differences in the wholesale selling prices of domestic and foreign articles in the principal markets of the United States; (3) advantages granted to a foreign producer by a foreign government, or by a person, partnership, corporation, or association in a foreign country; and (4) any other advantages or disadvantages in competition. Id. at 401–02 (quoting Tariff Act Sept. 21, 1922, ch. 356, § 315, 42 Stat. 166 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 486 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY required prior to the tariff adjustments, including public hearings.171 Further, Congress included restrictions prohibiting the “transfer of an article from the dutiable list to the free list or from the free list to the dutiable list, [or] a change in form of duty” and specified that the adjustments were subject to reversal when the requirements were no longer met.172 Thus, Congress delegated its power under detailed criteria in the Tariff Act and the Court utilized these standards when setting forth the “intelligible principle” doctrine.173 The Court further defined the “intelligible principle” concept in the more recent case, Mistretta v. United States, where it stated that in order for a delegation to be constitutionally valid, Congress must “clearly delineat[e] the general policy, the public agency which is to apply it, and the boundaries of this delegated authority.”174 The Court again found a constitutional delegation because in delegating authority to the United States Sentencing Commission to promulgate sentencing guidelines under the Sentencing Reform Act of 1984,175 Congress set forth numerous parameters. Using a formula similar to the Tariff Act, Congress articulated precise requirements for the formation of the sentencing guidelines,176 provided factors to be considered by the 941–943 (repealed 1930)). 171 Investigations to assist the President in ascertaining differences in costs of production under this section shall be made by the United States Tariff Commission, and no proclamation shall be issued under this section until such investigation shall have been made. The commission shall give reasonable public notice of its hearings and shall give reasonable opportunity to parties interested to be present, to produce evidence, and to be heard. Id. at 402. 172 Id. 173 See id. at 409. 174 Mistretta v. United States, 488 U.S. 361, 372–73 (1989) (quoting Am. Power & Light Co. v. SEC, 329 U.S. 90, 105 (1946)). 175 Sentencing Reform Act of 1984, 18 U.S.C. § 3551 et seq., 28 U.S.C. § 991–98 (2008). 176 Congress instructed the Commission that these sentencing ranges must be consistent with pertinent provisions of Title 18 of the United States Code and could not include sentences in excess of the NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 487 Commission,177 and set forth specific restrictions.178 Additionally, the Commission was given a list of what the newly formed guidelines were required to include.179 Because, “in addition to statutory maxima. Congress also required that for sentences of imprisonment, “the maximum of the range established for such a term shall not exceed the minimum of that range by more than the greater of 25 percent or 6 months, except that, if the minimum term of the range is 30 years or more, the maximum may be life imprisonment.” Moreover, Congress directed the Commission to use current average sentences “as a starting point” for its structuring of the sentencing ranges. Mistretta, 488 U.S. at 374–75 (citing 28 U.S.C. § 994). 177 To guide the Commission in its formulation of offense categories, Congress directed it to consider seven factors: the grade of the offense; the aggravating and mitigating circumstances of the crime; the nature and degree of the harm caused by the crime; the community view of the gravity of the offense; the public concern generated by the crime; the deterrent effect that a particular sentence may have on others; and the current incidence of the offense. Congress set forth 11 factors for the Commission to consider in establishing categories of defendants. These include the offender’s age, education, vocational skills, mental and emotional condition, physical condition (including drug dependence), previous employment record, family ties and responsibilities, community ties, role in the offense, criminal history, and degree of dependence upon crime for a livelihood. Id. at 375–76 (citing 28 U.S.C. § 994). 178 “Congress also prohibited the Commission from considering the ‘race, sex, national origin, creed, and socioeconomic status of offenders,’ and instructed that the guidelines should reflect the ‘general inappropriateness’ of considering certain other factors, such as current unemployment, that might serve as proxies for forbidden factors.” Id. at 376 (citing 28 U.S.C. § 994). 179 Congress mandated that the guidelines include: “(A) a determination whether to impose a sentence to probation, a fine, or a term of imprisonment; (B) a determination as to the appropriate amount of a fine or the appropriate length of a term of probation or a term of imprisonment; (C) a determination whether a sentence to a term of imprisonment should include a requirement that the defendant be placed on a term of supervised release after imprisonment, and, if so, the appropriate length of such a term; and (D) a determination whether multiple sentences to terms of imprisonment should be ordered to run concurrently or NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 488 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY these overarching constraints, Congress provided even more detailed guidance to the Commission,”180 the Court found that the intelligible principal standard had actually been exceeded and “in actuality [Congress] legislated a full hierarchy of punishment.”181 Nonetheless, the “intelligible principle” doctrine was reaffirmed and further elucidated by the Court.182 It is clear from both Hampton and Mistretta that in order to be constitutional, a congressional delegation must set forth more than a general directive.183 Rather, it must include definite standards to guide the agency in its decision-making.184 The absolute lack of standards in Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act is a glaring violation of the nondelegation doctrine. In fact, it is difficult to compare the Act to Hampton and Mistretta because there are virtually no guidelines in Section 102(c) on which to base a comparison.185 Both the Tariff Act and the Sentencing Reform Act began with specific requirements that had to be met in order for the designated authority to act.186 The only requirement in Section 102(c) is the wholly discretionary opinion of the Secretary that the action is “necessary to ensure expeditious construction of the barriers and roads.”187 This is hardly the same kind of standard upheld in Hampton and Mistretta. While the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act sets forth several factors to be considered in erecting the border fences,188 the Secretary is not directed to consecutively.” Id. at 374 n.8 (citing 28 U.S.C. § 994(a)(1)). 180 Id. at 376. 181 Id. at 377. 182 Id. at 372–77. 183 See id.; J.W. Hampton, Jr., & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 394 (1928). 184 See Mistretta, 488 U.S. 361; J.W. Hampton, 276 U.S. 394. 185 See Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act for Defense, the Global War on Terror, and Tsunami Relief, Pub. L. No. 109–13, § 102(c)(1), 119 Stat. 231 (2005). 186 See supra text accompanying notes 145, 154. 187 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act § 102(c)(1). 188 In general. In carrying out this section, the Secretary of NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 489 consider any factors in making his determination of statutory waivers.189 Thus, while the Secretary may choose to consider the aforementioned factors, the language of the Real ID Act does not require him to.190 Rather, the only guiding principle is his “sole discretion.”191 He is simply authorized to “waive all legal requirements.”192 This absence of any meaningful restriction on the Secretary’s authority is an unprecedented deviation from the “intelligible principle” standard. The district court’s finding that the specifications of areas of “high illegal entry,” deterring “illegal crossings,” and “necessary to ensure expeditious construction” constitute sufficient guiding principles is not convincing.193 Imagine a similar directive in Mistretta. Surely the Court would not have upheld a delegation to the Sentencing Commission to promulgate sentencing guidelines that the Commission, in its sole discretion, deemed necessary to punish criminals. Likewise, the Tariff Act delegation in Hampton would not have passed constitutional muster had it delegated power to the President to adjust any tariffs he deemed necessary in the interest of equality between domestic and foreign production or, even more akin to Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff, allowed the President to waive such tariffs. The holding in Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff is clearly at odds with both landmark nondelegation cases. At the same time, Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act bears a striking resemblance to legislation the Court has previously Homeland Security shall consult with the Secretary of the Interior, the Secretary of Agriculture, States, local governments, Indian tribes, and property owners in the United States to minimize the impact on the environment, culture, commerce, and quality of life for the communities and residents located near the sites at which such fencing is to be constructed. 8 U.S.C.A. § 1103 note (b)(1)(C)(i) (West 2009) (Improvement of Barriers at Border). 189 See Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act § 102(c)(1). 190 Id. 191 Id. 192 Id. 193 See supra notes 53–56 and accompanying text. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 490 struck down on nondelegation grounds.194 In Panama Refining Co. v. Ryan, the Court found the congressional delegation under Section 9(c) of the National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933195 “without constitutional authority.”196 In an effort to regulate the national oil industry, Section 9(c) delegated power to the President to enforce limits on oil transportation.197 However, similar to Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act, this delegation lacked a sufficient intelligible principle.198 The Court noted, “Section 9(c) does not state whether, or in what circumstances or under what conditions, the President is to [act under the given authority] . . . . It establishes no criterion to govern the President’s course . . . [and] does not require any finding by the President as a condition of his action.”199 Likewise, Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act provides no guide for when the Secretary may or may not exercise his statutory waiver authority. The district court found that the phrase “areas of high illegal entry,” in reference to fencing sites, constituted a 194 See Panama Refining Co. v. Ryan, 293 U.S. 388 (1935). National Industry Recovery Act, Pub. L. No. 73–67, § 9(c), 48 Stat. 195, 200 (1933), invalidated by A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495 (1935). 196 Panama Refining, 293 U.S. at 433. 197 (c) The President is authorized to prohibit the transportation in interstate and foreign commerce of petroleum and the products thereof produced or withdrawn from storage in excess of the amount permitted to be produced or withdrawn from storage by any state law or valid regulation or order prescribed thereunder, by any board, commission, officer, or other duly authorized agency of a State. Any violation of any order of the President issued under the provisions of this subsection shall be punishable by fine of not to exceed $ 1,000, or imprisonment for not to exceed six months, or both. National Industry Recovery Act § 9(c). 198 “As to the transportation of oil production in excess of state permission, the Congress has declared no policy, has established no standard, has laid down no rule. There is no requirement, no definition of circumstances and conditions in which the transportation is to be allowed or prohibited.” Panama Refining, 293 U.S. at 430. 199 Id. at 415. 195 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 491 sufficient guideline.200 However, there is no definition for this term anywhere within the Real ID Act.201 It is mentioned but once in the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act, without providing even general criteria.202 The other guideline, what the Secretary deems “necessary,”203 is even more subjective, open to almost limitless interpretation. The Court’s characterization of Section 9(c) in Panama Refining Co. is an all too apt description of Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act.204 Section 9(c) actually provided more direction by furnishing distinct rules for the President to follow,205 whereas the Real ID Act relegates decision-making to the Secretary’s sole discretion. Nonetheless, the Court in Panama Refining Co. held the delegation unconstitutional because it provided “the President an unlimited authority to determine the policy and to lay down the prohibition, or not to lay it down, as he may see fit.”206 This is precisely the type of authority Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act grants to the Secretary of Homeland Security. Panama Refining Co. is not the only example of the Court’s 207 incongruous treatment of Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff. In A. L. A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, the Court 200 Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff, 527 F. Supp. 2d 119, 128 (D.D.C. 2007). 201 See Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act for Defense, the Global War on Terror, and Tsunami Relief, Pub. L. No. 109-13, 119 Stat. 231 (2005). 202 8 U.S.C.A. § 1103 note (a) (West 2009) (Improvement of Barriers at Border). 203 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act § 102(c)(1). 204 Id.; see also supra notes 198–99 and accompanying text. 205 The President was required to use state laws, regulations, or orders as the benchmark for permitted transportation quantities. National Industry Recovery Act, Pub. L. No. 73-67, § 9(c), 48 Stat. 195, 200 (1933), invalidated by A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495 (1935). 206 Panama Refining Co. v. Ryan, 293 U.S. 388, 415 (1934). 207 See, e.g., Mistretta v. United States, 488 U.S. 361 (1988); A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495 (1935); J.W. Hampton, Jr., & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 394 (1928). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 492 struck down another unconstitutional congressional delegation.208 The legislation at issue in Schechter, Section 3 of the National Industrial Recovery Act,209 again bore a strong resemblance to Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act. Under Section 3, the President was granted authority to approve industry codes of “fair competition.”210 “Fair competition” was not defined in the National Industrial Recovery Act,211 just as “high illegal entry” and “necessary” are not defined in the Real ID Act.212 Due to 208 A.L.A. Schechter Poultry, 295 U.S. 495. National Industry Recovery Act § 3. 210 Id. (a) Upon the application to the President by one or more trade or industrial associations or groups, the President may approve a code or codes of fair competition for the trade or industry or subdivision thereof, represented by the applicant or applicants, if the President finds (1) that such associations or groups impose no inequitable restrictions on admission to membership therein and are truly representative of such trades or industries or subdivisions thereof, and (2) that such code or codes are not designed to promote monopolies or to eliminate or oppress small enterprises and will not operate to discriminate against them, and will tend to effectuate the policy of this title: Provided, That such code or codes shall not permit monopolies or monopolistic practices: Provided further, That where such code or codes affect the services and welfare of persons engaged in other steps of the economic process, nothing in this section shall deprive such persons of the right to be heard prior to approval by the President of such code or codes. The President may, as a condition of his approval of any such code, impose such conditions (including requirements for the making of reports and the keeping of accounts) for the protection of consumers, competitors, employees, and others, and in furtherance of the public interest, and may provide such exceptions to and exemptions from the provisions of such code, as the President in his discretion deems necessary to effectuate the policy herein declared. Id. § 3(a). 211 The Court struggled to find a definition, referencing sources such as the common law and the Federal Trade Commission Act. A.L.A. Schechter Poultry, 295 U.S. at 531–35. 212 See Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act for Defense, the Global War on Terror, and Tsunami Relief, Pub. L. No. 109-13, 119 Stat. 231 (2005). 209 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 493 the ambiguous language, the Court in Schechter found that Section 3 supplied “no standards for any trade, industry or activity.”213 Further, the Court held that it lacked sufficient guidelines “aside from the statement of the general aims of rehabilitation, correction and expansion described in section one.”214 A “statement of general aims” is precisely what Congress set forth in Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act. The Secretary is directed to use his discretion in furtherance of the broad goals of “deter[ing] illegal crossings”215 and “ensur[ing] expeditious construction” of barriers.216 It was exactly this sort of directive in Schechter that led the Court to hold, “[i]n view of the scope of that broad declaration, and of the nature of the few restrictions that are imposed, the discretion of the President . . . is virtually unfettered” and, therefore, “an unconstitutional delegation of legislative power.”217 This begs the obvious question of why the Court did not come to the same conclusion in Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff. The Secretary’s limitless statutory waiver authority is a clear violation of the nondelegation doctrine. Given the Court’s intelligible principle jurisprudence, it is clear that the congressional delegation in Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act is unconstitutional. IV. DETRIMENTAL RESULTS OF THE SUPREME COURT’S INACTION A. Environmental Effects The Secretary’s vast power is only exacerbated by the drastically limited options for review provided by the Real ID 218 Given the narrow restrictions placed on judicial Act. 213 A.L.A. Schechter Poultry, 295 U.S. at 541. Id. 215 8 U.S.C.A. § 1103 note (a) (West 2009) (Improvement of Barriers at Border). 216 Id. § 1103 note (c)(1). 217 A.L.A. Schechter Poultry, 295 U.S. at 541–42. 218 Emergency Supplemental Appropriations Act for Defense, the Global War on Terror, and Tsunami Relief, Pub. L. No. 109-13, § 102(c)(2), 119 Stat. 231 (2005). 214 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 494 intervention,219 the Court’s denial of certiorari was especially troublesome. Unfortunately, the Court’s inaction will likely have a lasting effect on the environment. Defenders of Wildlife warned that construction of the border fence in the SPRNCA would “fragment[] critical corridors for wildlife, including jaguars, black bear . . . and many other species.”220 This presents an especially dire situation for the endangered jaguars whose long-term survival is dependent upon their ability to roam over a large area.221 In addition, the fence would block “numerous desert washes feeding the San Pedro River and floodplain, resulting in erosion and sedimentation into the river, which provides habitat for hundreds of breeding, migratory, and wintering bird species, as well as more than 80 species of mammals.”222 Further, the Bureau of Land Management, whose initial Environmental Assessment (EA) found “no significant environmental impact,”223 subsequently issued a supplemental memorandum following a visit to the fence site.224 The memo expressed serious concerns about floods resulting from debris build-up on the fence.225 It continued, “[t]he timing and intensity of seasonal flood flows in the San Pedro River are essential for maintaining riparian function as well as recharging the alluvial aquifer. Regardless of the maintenance commitments by Border Patrol, the proposed/existing fence could inadvertently act as a flood control structure altering natural flood characteristics.”226 219 See supra text accompanying note 19. Border Fence Construction, supra note 141. 221 Joe Zentner, Jaguars on the Fence, DESERT USA, http://www.desert usa.com/mag06/dec/jaguars.html. 222 Border Fence Construction, supra note 141. 223 Defenders of Wildlife v. Chertoff, 527 F. Supp. 2d 119, 121 (D.D.C. 2007). 224 Memorandum from the Bureau of Land Management, BLM EA #AZ420-2007-051 Supplement (Oct. 4, 2007), available at http://www.biological diversity.org/programs/public_lands/rivers/san_pedro_river/pdfs/blm-foiaresp-040808-BLM-concerns-100407.pdf. 225 Id. 226 Id. 220 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 495 Notably, the supplemental memo was issued several weeks prior to Chertoff’s waiver.227 Chertoff only cited to the initial EA’s finding of “no significant environmental impact” in support of his waiver decision.228 Unfortunately, the memo proved to be an accurate predictor. In July of 2008, the combination of heavy rains and border fencing in southwestern Arizona resulted in severe flooding at the Organ Pipe Cactus National Monument.229 According to news reports, the flooding was caused by “debris and water backup [at the fence] during a . . . storm.”230 Just as many fence opponents feared, [r]apidly moving runoff in washes dislodged or eroded large chunks of concrete foundations, and debris stacking up against the fence itself created barriers or dams redirecting the water, creating gullies and causing even more erosion . . . . It created backwater pools up to seven feet deep and lateral flows several hundred feet wide that moved out of the washes, eroding some areas along patrol roads. The waters even scoured some fence and vehicle barrier foundations.231 Despite these seemingly prophetic events, fence construction at the SPRNCA continued. Unlike Organ Pipe Cactus National Monument, the plans for SPRNCA include movable barriers in the riverbed that may be removed to minimize affecting water 227 Determination Pursuant to Section 102 of the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act of 1996 as Amended by Section 102 of the REAL ID Act of 2005 and as Amended by the Secure Fence Act of 206, 72 Fed. Reg. 60,870 (Oct. 26, 2007). 228 Press Release, Dep’t of Homeland Sec., Department of Homeland Security: Statement Regarding Exercise of Waiver Authority (Oct. 2007), available at http://www.biologicaldiversity.org/programs/public_lands/rivers/ san_pedro_river/pdfs/dhs-EXEMPTION-statement-200710.pdf. 229 The flooding occurred at the port of entry at Lukeville, Arizona and Sonoyta Sonora, Mexico. Arthur H. Rotstein, Border Fence Causing Flooding Trouble, TUCSON CITIZEN, Aug. 24, 2008, http://www.tucson citizen.com/ss/local/94705.php. 230 Id. 231 Id. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 496 flow.232 However, recognizing the irony of placing removable barriers in an area known for flash floods, one critic stated, “[i]t’s a joke . . . [l]ike they’re going to anticipate when it’s going to flood and they’re going to go out and remove them.”233 Thus, the SPRNCA remains vulnerable to destruction similar to that experienced at Organ Pipe.234 B. Political Consequences While the environmental effects of the Court’s inaction are potentially devastating, so are the political ramifications if the Court stays this course. The “separation of powers framework was designed to prevent special interests from co-opting the government . . . . [T]hese special interests must convince three different groups with three different constituencies of the correctness of their proposals.”235 Consequently, the erosion of the separation of powers doctrine by Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act provides special interest groups with the ability to wield extensive influence simply by swaying the judgment of one individual. In Chadha, the Court recognized the danger in such a situation, noting that the purpose of congressional power to override a presidential veto is to “preclud[e] final arbitrary action of one person.”236 However, final arbitrary action is precisely what Chertoff exercised in his waiver of the twenty statutes.237 While the direct effects of Section 102(c) are disconcerting, 232 Howard Fischer, BLM: Border Barriers Would Harm San Pedro Area, EAST VALLEY TRIBUNE, Apr. 27, 2008, http://www.eastvalleytribune. com/story/114902. 233 Id. (quoting Sandy Bahr, Sierra Club). 234 See supra text accompanying notes 226, 231. 235 Michael G. Locklar, Is the 1996 Line-Item Veto Constitutional?, 34 HOUS. L. REV. 1161, 1179 (1997). 236 Immigration & Naturalization Serv. v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919, 951 (1983). 237 See Determination Pursuant to Section 102 of the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act of 1996 as Amended by Section 102 of the REAL ID Act of 2005 and as Amended by the Secure Fence Act of 206, 72 Fed. Reg. 60,870 (Oct. 26, 2007). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 497 an even larger potential problem exists if the Court stays the course of inaction while similar unconstitutional legislation is enacted. The danger in violating the separation of powers doctrine and, thus, allowing special interest groups increased power over legislation is embodied in the very title of these groups. Special interests strive to further the goals of specific sects of society, as opposed to the general public.238 Because these groups vary in size and funding, the more powerful groups tend to be those with the most funding.239 A system that facilitates the interests of the affluent while ignoring those with less means drastically deviates from the Framers’ vision of equal representation and protection from “improvident laws.”240 However, well-funded special interests are not the only danger associated with the deterioration of the separation of powers doctrine. Political parties also represent different sects of society, at times greatly at odds with one another. Upon its first introduction, the Real ID Act was passed in the House of Representatives with ninety-six percent of Republicans voting for it and seventy-eight percent of Democrats voting against it.241 238 Some well known special interest groups include the National Association for the Advancement of Colored People (NAACP), AntiDefamation League, and Gay and Lesbian Advocates and Defenders (GLAD). Political Advocacy Groups, A Directory of United States Lobbyists, http://www.vancouver.wsu.edu/fac/kfountain/alpha.html (last visited Sept. 28, 2009). 239 A Fortune Magazine survey confirmed “the more money a group spent on its plain old lobbying efforts in Washington, the more influence it wielded.” Jeffrey H. Birnbaum, Follow the Money. Hard Money. Soft Money. Lobbying Money. Which Buys the Most Influence in Washington? FORTUNE’s Power 25 Survey Attempts an Answer and Ranks the Top Lobbying Groups, FORTUNE, Dec. 6, 1999. According to Fortune’s Power 25 survey, the American Association of Retired Persons (AARP) was the most powerful lobbying group, while the National Rifle Association was tied for second place. Id. 240 Chadha, 462 U.S. at 951. 241 Brian Murphy, The Real ID Act of 2005: Tightening the Burden on Asylum Seekers, Federal Standards for Driver’s Licenses, and Patching a Hole in a Border Fence at the Cost of Other Legislation, 19 GEO. IMMIGR. L.J. 191, 191 (2004) (citations omitted). The bill was not passed due to opposition in the Senate. See supra note 2 and accompanying text. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 498 This disparity illustrates the profound divide between the two political parties. It also serves as a warning against granting sweeping authority to one individual. Despite the expected uneven distribution of representatives in Congress, the presence of both parties encourages dialogue and debate regarding important legislative matters. In stark contrast, the delegation of broad authority to one individual requires no debate. Legislation, such as Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act, leaves important legislative matters to the discretion of one individual and, consequently, the unfettered will of one political party. Ironically, the Court’s negligence in addressing this violation of separation of powers means that the solution will likely come from exertion of political party power. V. A CONGRESSIONAL SOLUTION TO THE COURT’S FAILURE AS A LEGISLATIVE CHECK Fortunately, some legislators are aware of the unconstitutionality of Section 102(c).242 As illustrated by the original House vote in 2005, the majority of those legislators are Democrats.243 In fact, in June of 2007 U.S. Rep. Raul Grijalva, D-Ariz., introduced legislation that would have repealed the Secretary’s waiver authority granted under the Real ID Act.244 The Borderlands Conservation and Security Act245 not only provided for the outright repeal of Section 102(c) of the Illegal Immigration Reform and Immigrant Responsibility Act of 1996, but also required the Secretary to: develop a border protection strategy that supports the border security needs of the United States in a manner that best protects—(A) units of the National Park System; (B) National Forest System land; (C) land under the 242 Forty-eight U.S. Representatives, all of whom were Democrats, cosponsored the Borderlands Conservation and Security Act that, if passed, would have repealed Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act. Borderlands Conservation and Security Act of 2007, H.R. 2593, 110th Cong. (2007). 243 See supra text accompanying note 241. 244 H.R. 2593. 245 Id. NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 499 jurisdiction of the Bureau of Land Management; (D) land under the jurisdiction of the United States Fish and Wildlife Service; and (E) other relevant land under the jurisdiction of the Department of the Interior or the Department of Agriculture.246 U.S. Rep. Earl Blumenauer, a fellow Democrat, expressed support for the bill, stating “[i]t is unprecedented that a single person can be above the law without any judicial appeal or remedy . . . . And it is absurd to claim that he must waive the Safe Drinking Water Act and Clean Air Act, to name a few, in order to build this border fence.”247 Unfortunately, the bill stalled in committee shortly after its introduction.248 As a result it was “cleared from the books” upon termination of the 110th congressional session.249 There is still hope that the Democratic 250 victory in the recent election may revive the bill or lead to similar legislation.251 This corrective legislative action is necessary due to the Court’s failure to perform its duty as a legislative check. While such congressional action would correct 246 Id. § 4(a)(1). The Secretary is directed to develop the protection plan in cooperation with the Secretary of the Interior and the Secretary of Agriculture. Id. 247 David McLemore, Fight Over Border Fence Environmental Waivers Could Reach Supreme Court, DALLAS MORNING NEWS, Apr. 15, 2008, (quoting U.S. Rep. Earl Blumenauer, D-Ore.). 248 The Bill was referred to the Committee on Homeland Security, Committee on Natural Resources, and Committee on Agriculture on June 6, 2007. H.R. 2593. 249 GovTrack, H.R. 2593: Borderlands Conservation and Security Act of 2007, http://www.govtrack.us/congress/bill.xpd?bill=h110-2593 (last visited Sept. 28, 2009). 250 The Democratic Party won majority control of both Houses of Congress in 2008. House of Representatives Big Board Election Results 2008, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 9, 2008, http://elections.nytimes.com/2008/results/house/ votes.html; Senate Big Board Election Results 2008, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 9, 2008, http://elections.nytimes.com/2008/results/senate/votes.html. 251 Legislation has already been introduced in the House and Senate that would repeal Title II of the Real Id Act, the section requiring national ID cards. REAL ID Repeal and Identification Security Enhancement Act of 2009, H.R. 3471, 111th Cong. (2009); Providing for Additional Security in States’ Identification Act of 2009, S. 1261, 111th Cong. (2009). NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 500 the separation of powers violation, it is likely too late to mitigate the damage to border lands and wildlife. The 670 miles of border fence originally slated for December 31, 2008 completion252 are now nearly finished.253 Additionally, Rep. Grijalva admits that the poor state of the economy254 means the Act is no longer a congressional priority.255 Unfortunately, Section 102(c) of the Real ID Act may now be relegated to serving as a warning beacon for future legislators. If Congress recognizes its prior error, it may be more cautious before enacting future legislation that threatens the separation of powers doctrine. As Professor Jonathan Turley, a constitutional law scholar at George Washington University explained, “there is no evidence Congress considered the implications of giving Homeland Security such broad waiver power.”256 As Congress now realizes the consequences of granting such sweeping authority, it may be more diligent in analyzing the effects of future delegations. The full environmental cost of this lesson remains to be seen, but its 252 See supra note 22 and accompanying text. See Department of Homeland Security, Southwest Border Fence Construction Status Map, http://www.cbp.gov/linkhandler/cgov/newsroom/ highlights/fence_map.ctt/fence_map.pdf (last visited Sept. 29, 2009). 254 See Edmund L. Andrews, Fed Chief Defends Steps Taken to Contain Crisis, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 18, 2009. 255 “There’s a shift in priorities now with the economy . . . . Throwing $450 million at a fence pales in comparison to fixing our economy.” Melissa Del Bosque, Back to the Wall, TEXAS OBSERVER, Feb. 6, 2009 (quoting U.S. Rep. Raul Grijalva). 256 McLemore, supra note 247 (quoting Prof. Jonathan Turley, George Washington University). Professor Turley: is a nationally recognized legal scholar who has written extensively in areas ranging from constitutional law to legal theory to tort law . . . . He has served as a consultant on homeland security and constitutional issues, and is a frequent witness before the House and Senate on constitutional and statutory issues as well as tort reform legislation. George Washington University Law School, Jonathan Turley, http://www. law.gwu.edu/Faculty/profile.aspx?id=1738 (last visited Sept. 30, 2009). 253 NIELSEN REVISED.DOC 4/28/2010 11:39 AM LOCKING DOWN OUR BORDERS 501 significance should not be underestimated.257 As one Defender’s of Wildlife representative stated, “[w]hen you disregard environmental laws, it leads to real adverse impacts . . . . It’s not just an academic argument.”258 257 See supra text accompanying notes 226, 231. Del Bosque, supra note 255 (quoting Defenders of Wildlife federal lands associate Noah Kahn). 258 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK: HOW MANDATING THE HUMAN PAPILLOMAVIRUS VACCINE WILL INCREASE THE USE OF VACCINE EXEMPTIONS AND NEGATIVELY IMPACT OUR NATION’S HEALTH By Katharine Southard* INTRODUCTION A 7-year-old boy went on a family trip to Switzerland in January 2008.1 Upon arriving back home to San Diego, he caused a measles outbreak in the city.2 His parents had chosen not to vaccinate him or his siblings,3 and as a result, he infected at least eleven additional children, ranging in age from ten months to nine years old.4 All eleven cases were unvaccinated, including eight whose parents had claimed personal belief exemptions.5 *B.A., Harvard University, 2003; J.D., Brooklyn Law School, expected 2010. The author wishes to thank her husband, Eric, for his encouragement, love and patience. She also wishes to thank her parents for their constant support, love and guidance. Finally, she would like to thank the Journal of Law and Policy for their editorial assistance. 1 A. Hassidim et al., Outbreak of Measles—San Diego, California, January-February 2008, 57 MORBIDITY & MORTALITY WEEKLY REPORT, 203, 203 (2008). 2 Rong-Gong Lin II & Sandra Poindexter, California Schools’ Risks Rise as Vaccinations Drop, LOS ANGELES TIMES, Mar. 29, 2009. 3 Id. 4 Miriam E. Tucker, San Diego Measles Outbreak Shows the Effect of Vaccine Exemptions, PEDIATRIC NEWS, Mar. 1, 2008, at 14. 5 Id. 503 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 504 The development of vaccines has greatly improved our nation’s health.6 In order to realize the full benefits of the vaccines, states within the United States have mandated vaccines since the nineteenth century;7 however, not all children are necessarily subject to these mandates.8 All fifty states allow for medical exemptions from vaccine requirements, such as a serious allergy to a vaccine component, and most states also allow for religious exemptions.9 For example, in August 2008, Rita Palma, a mother from Bayport, Long Island, requested that the town’s Board of Education allow her son to enter the sixth grade without being immunized, claiming that vaccinations were against her religious beliefs.10 She stated that “[v]accinations represent fear, anxiety and mistrust in God,” and that the idea of vaccinations “contradicts the peace and balance [she] seek[s] in [her] journey to God.”11 Besides medical and religious exemptions, twenty-one states also grant exemptions for parents who claim philosophical or personal objections to immunization.12 Some states make these philosophical exemptions easy to obtain, while other states require “notarization, annual renewal, a signature from a local health official, or a personally written letter from a parent.”13 Additionally, many parents of young children are worried that 6 See LAWRENCE O. GOSTIN, PUBLIC HEALTH LAW: POWER, DUTY, RESTRAINT 376 (2d ed. 2008). 7 See James G. Hodge, Jr. & Lawrence O. Gostin, School Vaccination Requirements: Historical, Social, and Legal Perspectives, 90 KY. L.J. 831, 851 (2002) (“The Commonwealth of Massachusetts incorporated its own school [smallpox] vaccination law in 1855, New York in 1862, Connecticut in 1872, and Pennsylvania in 1895.”). 8 Paul Offit, Fatal Exemption: Relationship Between Vaccine Exemptions and Rates of Disease, CENTERS FOR DISEASE CONTROL AND PREVENTION, Jan. 29, 2007, http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/vac-gen/laws/fatal-exemption. htm. 9 Id.; see infra note 132 and accompanying text. 10 Joie Tyrrell, Taking Another Shot, NEWSDAY, Aug. 13, 2008, at A08. 11 Id. 12 Bloomberg News, More Kids Not Getting Shots, NEWSDAY, May 7, 2009, at A25. 13 Offit, supra note 8. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 505 vaccinations may cause autism, and therefore cite this as a personal reason not to vaccinate their child.14 Many parents, including Erin Micklo from Illinois, believe that the measles, mumps and rubella (“MMR”) vaccination had a negative effect on their children.15 Micklo recalls that “[w]ithin a couple of days of being vaccinated, the 18-month-old boy developed a high fever and a rash and became extremely lethargic.”16 Her son was later diagnosed with autism.17 In the face of frequent parental concern, the Centers for Disease Control (“CDC”) report that “vaccines are not associated with [autism].”18 Regardless, more parents are opting not to have children vaccinated with all of the shots health officials recommend.19 14 Neil Osterweil, US Measles Increase Due to Declining Vaccinations, MEDSCAPE MEDICAL NEWS, Aug. 28, 2008, http://www.medscape.com/ viewarticle/579800. Autism is a “severe developmental disorder” that may begin at birth or within the first few years of life. What is Autism?, http://www.autism.com/autism/index.htm (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). Most autistic children engage in puzzling behavior that differs from behavior of typical children. Id. There is no single best treatment for all children with autism, but research shows that early intervention treatment services can greatly improve a child’s development. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Treatment of Autism Spectrum Disorders, http://www.cdc.gov/ ncbddd/autism/treatment.html (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). 15 Deborah L. Shelton & Deanese Williams-Harris, Kids’ Vaccinations Face Risky Resistance Pediatricians Fear That Concerns About Immunization Will Allow Once Vanquished Childhood Diseases to Return, CHI. TRIB., Aug. 26, 2008, at 1. 16 Id. 17 Id. 18 Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Topics Related to Autism Spectrum Disorders, http://www.cdc.gov/ncbddd/autism/topics.html (last visited Sept. 25, 2009) [hereinafter CDC, Topics Related to Autism]. Scientists at Columbia University Mailman School of Public Health’s Center for Infection and Immunity and researchers at the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Massachusetts General Hospital, and Trinity College Dublin also conducted a study, which showed no connection between the MMR vaccine and autism. See Study Firmly Shows No Connection Between Measles, Mumps, Rubella MMR Vaccine and Autism, HEALTH & MED. WK. 3384 (2008). 19 Bloomberg News, supra note 12. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 506 Due to these parents’ decisions to withhold their children from receiving certain vaccinations, the number of unvaccinated children is growing in states that allow parents to exempt their own kids for personal reasons, leading to outbreaks of measles and pertussis (whooping cough).20 During the first seven months of the year 2008, 131 measles cases in the United States were reported to the CDC.21 This is the highest level of infection during the same period in any year since 1996.22 Of those 131 measles cases, 112 victims were either unvaccinated or had no evidence of inoculation.23 Two thirds of the cases did not receive the measles vaccination for religious or philosophical reasons.24 With decreasing vaccination rates, two population groups are most susceptible to an epidemic because they are most likely to not be vaccinated: home schooled children and those who hold certain beliefs that do not allow vaccination.25 Additionally, because measles “is so contagious, [it] is one of the first diseases to reappear when immunization coverage declines.”26 This importance of the MMR vaccine is illustrated by the fact that measles caused approximately 450 annual deaths and 48,000 hospitalizations in the United States before the creation of the measles vaccine in the mid-1960s.27 20 Id. Editorial, Measles Returns, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 24, 2008, at WK8. 22 Id. 23 Osterweil, supra note 14. 24 Id. 25 US Measles Increase Caused by Vacc Scare, PHARMA MARKETLETTER, Sept. 1, 2008. 26 Editorial, supra note 21. 27 Osterweil, supra note 14. Common symptoms of measles include rash, fever, cough, and runny nose. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Overview of Measles, http://www.cdc.gov/measles/about/ overview/html (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). However, approximately 20% of those infected report more serious complications including ear infections (one out of every 10 children), pneumonia (one out of 20 children), and encephalitis (one out of every 1,000 children). Id. Encephalitis is an inflammation of the brain that can lead to convulsions and can cause a child to become deaf or mentally retarded. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Complications of Measles, http://www.cdc.gov/measles/about/ 21 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 507 Similarly, whooping cough cases have also increased recently.28 A recent study suggests that children are twenty-three times more likely to get whooping cough if they are not vaccinated against the disease.29 The co-authors of the study state that, “[t]he results dispel vaccine-refusing parents’ belief ‘that their children are not at risk for preventable diseases.’”30 Measles and whooping cough are just two of the many diseases that children are vaccinated against.31 In recent years, the number of mandated vaccinations has increased so that children now may get as many as thirty-three inoculations to prevent fifteen diseases.32 A new vaccine has recently been added to that list.33 In June 2006, the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) announced the approval of Gardasil®, “the first vaccine developed to prevent cervical cancer, precancerous genital lesions and genital warts due to human complications.html (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). Further, for every 1,000 children who get measles, one or two will die from it. Id. “Measles also can make a pregnant woman have a miscarriage, give birth prematurely, or have a low-birth-weight baby.” Id. 28 Study: Pertussis Shots Work, NEWSDAY, May 26, 2009, at A29. “In 2007, 10,454 cases were reported nationwide, including 10 children who died.” Id. 29 Id. 30 Id. 31 See ANDREW T. KROGER ET AL., CTRS. FOR DISEASE CONTROL AND PREVENTION, GENERAL RECOMMENDATIONS ON IMMUNIZATION: RECOMMENDATIONS OF THE ADVISORY COMMITTEE ON IMMUNIZATION PRACTICES 3 (2006). The Advisory Committee on Immunization Practices (ACIP) “develops written recommendations for the routine administration of vaccines to children and adults in the civilian population; recommendations include age for vaccine administration number of doses and dosing interval, and precautions and contraindications.” Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Vaccines: ACIP, http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/recs/acip/ default.htm (last visited Sept. 25, 2009) [hereinafter CDC, Advisory Committee on Immunization Practices]. 32 Bloomberg News, supra note 12. 33 See Press Release, Food and Drug Admin., FDA Licenses New Vaccine for Prevention of Cervical Cancer and Other Diseases in Females Caused by Human Papillomavirus (June 8, 2006), available at http://www. fda.gov/NewsEvents/Newsroom/PressAnnouncements/2006/ucm108666.htm. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 508 papillomavirus (HPV) types 6, 11, 16 and 18.”34 During the following year, in 2007, “at least 24 states and D.C. introduced legislation to specifically mandate the HPV vaccine for school.”35 Among these twenty-four states, only Virginia and D.C. have moved toward requiring sixth-grade girls to receive the vaccination.36 Both Virginia and D.C. passed laws in 2007, but “pushed back their start dates to [2009] to allow more study of the vaccine.”37 Although the HPV vaccine may reduce the incidence of HPV and cervical cancer, there is great debate over mandating the vaccine.38 Parents and guardians object to the HPV vaccine for different reasons than those who object to vaccines such as the MMR vaccine.39 While some opponents of mandatory HPV vaccination for school admission maintain that mandatory vaccination preempts parental authority to make health decisions for one’s child, or that the safety of the vaccine is still in doubt, others morally object to required vaccines for a sexually transmitted disease.40 According to the first national survey 34 Id. National Conference of State Legislatures, HPV Vaccine, http://www. ncsl.org/IssuesResearch/Health/HPVVaccineStateLegislation (last visited Sept. 25, 2009) [hereinafter NCSL, HPV Vaccine]. 36 Dena Potter, HPV Vaccine a Suggestion, Not Mandate in DC, VA, NEWSDAY, Sept. 1, 2009, at A35. 37 Id. The Virginia legislature passed a school vaccine requirement in 2007, and considered a bill that would delay that requirement, but the Senate Committee declined to take action on the bill. NCSL, HPV Vaccine, supra note 35; S. 722, 2008 Session (Va. 2008). 38 See, e.g., Cheryl A. Vamos et al., The HPV Vaccine: Framing the Arguments FOR and AGAINST Mandatory Vaccination of All Middle School Girls, 78 J. SCH. HEALTH 302 (2008); Linda Marsa, Gardasil’s Chorus of Doubters, L.A. TIMES, Aug. 11, 2008, at 1. 39 See generally Amanda Gardner, Many Moms Unwilling to Have Younger Daughters Get HPV Vaccine, HEALTH DAY (May 5, 2008) (finding that parents are likely to object to vaccination because of doubts of its effectiveness to prevent cervical cancer and because they believed it would cause the child to engage in riskier sexual behavior). 40 Rachel Meisterman, Note, The Aftermath of the Introduction of the Human Papillomavirus Vaccination, 3 J. HEALTH & BIOMEDICAL L. 313, 331 35 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 509 measuring attitudes towards the HPV vaccine since its FDA approval in 2006, “only half of American mothers intend to have their teenaged daughters vaccinated against human papillomavirus (HPV) if the girls are under the age of 13, despite government guidelines that suggest the opposite.”41 Further, “[u]nlike other diseases for which state legislatures have mandated vaccination for children, HPV is neither transmissible through casual contact nor potentially fatal during childhood.”42 Because of the differences between the HPV vaccination and vaccinations that prevent airborne diseases, the District of Columbia and Virginia—who have passed legislation requiring the HPV vaccination for females—have included broad opt-out provisions in their statutes.43 The District of Columbia’s legislation allows the parent or legal guardian to opt out “for any reason.”44 Similarly, Virginia’s legislation allows parents or guardians to refuse the HPV vaccination for their daughter “after having reviewed materials describing the link between the human papillomavirus and cervical cancer approved for such use by the Board.”45 Because of the current resistance by parents to vaccinate their daughters at a young age,46 many parents will likely exercise their right to opt-out. This Note argues that the ease of which a parent can decide against vaccinating their child with the HPV vaccine may then (2007). 41 Gardner, supra note 39. The CDC currently recommends the vaccine for all eleven and twelve-year-old girls, and for females aged thirteen through twenty-six years old who have not been previously vaccinated or who have not completed the full series of shots. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, HPV Vaccine-Questions & Answers for the Public, http://www. cdc.gov/vaccines/vpd-vac/hpv/hpv-vacsafe-effic.htm (last visited Oct. 18, 2009) [hereinafter CDC, Questions & Answers for the Public]. 42 Gail Javitt et al., Assessing Mandatory HPV Vaccination: Who Should Call the Shots?, 36 J.L. MED. & ETHICS 384, 384 (2008). 43 See VA. CODE ANN. § 32.1–46(D) (West 2008); see also D.C. CODE § 7–1651.04(b)(1)(B)(iii)(2001). 44 D.C. CODE § 7–1651.04(b)(1)(B)(iii). 45 VA. CODE ANN. § 32.1–46 (D)(3). 46 See Gardner, supra note 39. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 510 encourage parents to seek exemptions for other vaccines, thus causing re-emergence of diseases like measles and whooping cough. Partly due to parents’ concerns that vaccines are linked to rising rates of autism, more parents are opting not to have their children vaccinated.47 Giving parents the option to decline the HPV vaccine with such ease may provide additional encouragement for parents to decline other vaccinations for their children as well. Including such broad opt-out provisions in state statutes, as the District of Columbia and Virginia have done, may ultimately result in a disastrous return of childhood diseases. Part I of this Note provides background information on HPV and its link to cervical cancer, as well as information on the HPV vaccine, Gardasil®. Part II examines the foundational case of Jacobson v. Massachusetts48 and the current use of exemptions in the anti-vaccination movement. Part III discusses the actions taken thus far by state legislatures regarding the HPV vaccine and the various objections to mandating the HPV vaccine for school entry. Part III further concludes that mandating the HPV vaccine with broad opt-out provisions could encourage parents and guardians to then seek exemptions to other previously mandated vaccines which protect against diseases that are communicable in a school setting. Finally, Part IV concludes that although the approval of a vaccine against cancer-causing HPV strains is a tremendous development, mandating the HPV vaccine for school entry while including broad opt-out provisions may actually undermine our nation’s health. I. BACKGROUND A. Human Papillomavirus Virus Each year 6.2 million people become infected with human papillomavirus (HPV), the most common sexually transmitted 47 48 Bloomberg News, supra note 12. 197 U.S. 11 (1905). SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 511 infection.49 Seventy-four percent of those infected are between the ages of fifteen and twenty-four.50 This is in addition to the approximately twenty million Americans who are already infected.51 Over fifty percent of sexually active men and women acquire genital HPV at some point throughout their lives,52 and women have an eighty percent chance of getting HPV by the time they are fifty years of age.53 At least thirty of the more than 100 types of HPV can be passed from one person to another through sexual contact.54 Since most HPV infections are asymptomatic,55 many people are unaware when they have become infected with HPV.56 As a result, most infected individuals do not realize that they are passing the virus to a partner since the virus may be transmitted even when it’s asymptomatic.57 In ninety percent of cases, “the body’s immune system clears the HPV infection naturally within two years;”58 however, some cases of HPV infection persist for many years and may cause cell abnormalities, increasing a woman’s risk of developing cervical cancer.59 HPV types can be classified into two types: “low-risk” and 49 Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Genital HPV Infection, http://www.cdc.gov/std/HPV/STDFact-HPV.htm (last visited Oct. 24, 2009) [hereinafter CDC, Genital HPV]. 50 LAURI E. MARKOWITZ ET AL., CTRS. FOR DISEASE CONTROL AND PREVENTION, QUADRIVALENT HUMAN PAPILLOMAVIRUS VACCINE 4 (2007). 51 CDC, Genital HPV, supra note 49. 52 Id. 53 CDC, Questions & Answers for the Public, supra note 41. 54 National Cancer Institute, Human Papillomavirus and Cancer, http://www.cancer.gov/cancertopics/factsheet/Risk/HPV/ (last visited Oct. 24, 2009) [hereinafter NCI, HPV and Cancer]. Although the surest way to avoid risk of developing HPV is to refrain from sexual contact, a study among newly sexually active college women demonstrated a 70 percent reduction in HPV infection when their partners used condoms. MARKOWITZ ET AL., supra note 50, at 7. 55 NCI, HPV and Cancer, supra note 54. 56 CDC, Genital HPV, supra note 49. 57 Id. 58 Id. 59 NCI, HPV and Cancer, supra note 54. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 512 “high-risk,” depending on whether or not they cause lesions that develop into cancer.60 “Both high-risk and low-risk types of HPV can cause the growth of abnormal cells, but only the highrisk types [such as types sixteen and eighteen] of HPV lead to cancer.”61 The American Cancer Society estimates that in 2009, 11,270 women will be diagnosed with cervical cancer, and approximately 4,070 women will die from cervical cancer in the United States.62 Still, the incidence of cervical cancer in the United States is very low compared with other parts of the world.63 Each year, eighty-five percent of the roughly 473,000 cervical cancer cases worldwide afflict women in developing countries.64 Of those 65 473,000 cases, an estimated 253,500 lead to deaths. In many developing countries, cervical cancer is the greatest cause of cancer-related deaths among women,66 primarily because developing countries lack the screening and treatment programs that exist in the United States.67 B. Gardasil® Vaccine In 2006, the FDA approved Merck & Co.’s Gardasil®, a vaccine for females that is effective in preventing infection with HPV types six, eleven, sixteen, and eighteen.68 The vaccine does 60 Id. Id. “These high-risk types of HPV cause growths on the cervix that are usually flat and nearly invisible, as compared with the external warts caused by low-risk types HPV-6 and HPV-11.” Id. 62 American Cancer Society, Detailed Guide: Cervical Cancer, http://www.cancer.org/docroot/CRI/content/CRI_2_4_1X_What_are_the_key _statistics_for_cervical_cancer_8.asp?rnav=cri (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). 63 See National Cervical Cancer Coalition, http://www.nccc-online.org (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). 64 Id. 65 Id. 66 Id. 67 Javitt et al., supra note 42, at 385. 68 U.S. FOOD AND DRUG ADMIN., GARDASIL PACKAGE INSERT (2009) [hereinafter GARDASIL PACKAGE INSERT]. GlaxoSmithKline is awaiting FDA 61 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 513 not protect against all strains of HPV, but HPV types sixteen and eighteen are responsible for about seventy percent of cervical cancer cases worldwide.69 The CDC currently recommends the vaccine for all eleven- and twelve-year-old girls, and for females aged thirteen through twenty-six years old “who have not been previously vaccinated or who have not completed the full series of shots.”70 The vaccine consists of three injections, during a six-month period, and may be given at the same time as other vaccines.71 While the CDC claims that the HPV vaccine does not appear to cause any major side effects,72 there were 15,037 reports of adverse events following Gardasil® vaccination made to the CDC’s Vaccine Adverse Event Reporting System (VAERS) as of September 1, 2009.73 Of these, ninety-three percent were classified as reports of nonserious events,74 and seven percent as serious events.75 Common complaints include pain, redness or swelling at the injection site.76 However, there have been 44 U.S. reports of death among approval on its vaccine, Cervarix. NCSL, HPV Vaccine, supra note 35. 69 NCI, HPV and Cancer, supra note 54. The other two HPV types targeted by the vaccine—HPV-6 and HPV-11—cause approximately ninety percent of the cases of genital warts. Id. 70 Ctrs. for Disease Control and Prevention, HPV Vaccine- Questions & Answers, http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/vpd-vac/hpv/vac-faqs.htm (last visited Oct. 18, 2009). The recommendation “allows for vaccination to begin at age nine” and the CDC stresses that the “vaccine is most effective for girls/women who get vaccinated before their first sexual contact.” Id. 71 Id. 72 Press Release, Ctrs. for Disease Control and Prevention, HPV Vaccine: What You Need to Know (Feb. 2, 2007), available at http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/pubs/vis/downloads/vis-hpv.pdf. 73 Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Reports of Health Concerns Following HPV Vaccination, http://www.cdc.gov/vaccinesafety/ vaers/gardasil.htm (last visited Oct. 24, 2009) [hereinafter CDC, Health Concerns Following Vaccination]. As of September 1, 2009, more than 26 million doses of Gardasil were distributed in the United States. Id. 74 Id. Non-serious adverse events have included fainting, arm pain and swelling at the injection site, headache, nausea and fever. Id. 75 Id. 76 Id. Eight out of ten individuals complain of pain at the injection site and one out of four individuals complain of redness or swelling at the SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 514 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY females who have received the vaccine.77 Still, of the 27 reports of death that have been confirmed, there was nothing to suggest that they were caused by the vaccine.78 Guillain-Barré Syndrome (GBS), a rare neurological disorder that causes muscle weakness, has also been reported in individuals following vaccination with Gardasil®.79 There were 36 reported cases of GBS by girls after HPV vaccination in the U.S. from 2006 to 2008.80 In seventy-five percent of those cases, the disorder occurred within six weeks after receiving the vaccination.81 However, the CDC reports that there is no evidence that Gardasil® has increased the rate of GBS above that expected in the population,82 but “the fact that most of [the] cases occurred within six weeks of vaccination does warrant careful monitoring for any additional cases and continued analysis.”83 Further, while thromboembolic disorders (blood clots) have been reported to VAERS, most of these individuals had risk factors for blood clots, such as use of oral contraceptives, which are known to increase the risk of 84 clotting. However, one known side effect associated with the HPV vaccine, fainting, caused the FDA to require that vaccine manufacturer Merck & Co. add a warning to the vaccine’s package insert.85 The warning now recommends that patients be injection site. Id. 77 Id. 78 Id. 79 Id. 80 Researchers: Guillain-Barre Syndrome After HPV Vaccine Needs Monitoring, OBESITY, FITNESS & WELLNESS WK. 3272 (2009) [hereinafter Monitoring of Guillain-Barre Syndrome]. As of September 1, 2009, more than 26 million doses of Gardasil were distributed in the United States. CDC, Health Concerns Following Vaccination, supra note 73. 81 Id. 82 CDC, Health Concerns Following Vaccination, supra note 73. GBS “occurs in 1–2 out of every 100,000 people in their teens.” Id. 83 Monitoring of Guillain-Barre Syndrome, supra note 80. 84 CDC, Health Concerns Following Vaccination, supra note 73. 85 Steven Reinberg, 25% of Teen Girls Vaccinated for HPV, HEALTH SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 515 observed “for 15 minutes after administration” of the vaccine.86 The CDC and the FDA plan to continue to monitor the safety of Gardasil® as is customary with approved vaccines.87 II. HISTORY OF VACCINATION AND SCHOOL VACCINATION REQUIREMENTS A. The Foundations of Public Health Law and Mandatory Immunizations: Jacobson v. Massachusetts88 The Tenth Amendment of the U.S. Constitution states: “the powers not delegated to the United States by the Constitution, nor prohibited by it to the States, are reserved to the States respectively, or to the people.”89 These powers include a state’s “police powers” which “relate to the safety, health, morals and general welfare of the public.”90 While protecting the public’s health, a state “is limited by individual rights to autonomy, privacy, liberty, property, and other legally protected interests.”91 Balancing an individual’s constitutional rights with the duty of the state to protect the public’s health “poses an enduring problem for public health law.”92 Vaccination programs are a “core component” of public health in the United States, supported by state legal requirements, federal funding and oversight.93 Each state has school vaccination laws mandating vaccination of children for certain diseases.94 Communicable diseases, for which there are DAY, Oct. 9, 2008. 86 GARDASIL PACKAGE INSERT, supra note 68. 87 CDC, Health Concerns Following Vaccination, supra note 73. 88 197 U.S. 11 (1905). 89 U.S. CONST. amend. X. 90 Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45, 53 (1905). 91 GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 11. 92 Id. 93 Hodge & Gostin, supra note 7, at 833. 94 See CTRS. FOR DISEASE CONTROL AND PREVENTION, CHILDCARE AND SCHOOL IMMUNIZATION REQUIREMENTS, 2005–2006 (2006), available at http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/vac-gen/laws/downloads/izlaws05-06.pdf SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 516 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY vaccines, have dramatically decreased since the introduction of school vaccination laws.95 Mandatory immunization laws in the United States first appeared in the early nineteenth century96 in an effort to combat outbreaks of smallpox.97 In 1827, Boston became the first city to require vaccination for all children entering public schools98 and by the late nineteenth century, the trend toward compulsory child vaccination as a condition of school attendance spread to the midwestern and western states.99 In 1905, the U.S. Supreme Court made what is “widely regarded as the seminal decision in American public health law”100 in Jacobson v. Massachusetts,101 and set the standard for 102 Proceeding under the state mandatory vaccination laws. statutes of Massachusetts, the Board of Health of Cambridge adopted a regulation mandating the smallpox vaccination for “all the inhabitants of Cambridge” in February 1902.103 Jacobson, who refused the vaccination, argued that “a compulsory vaccination law is unreasonable, arbitrary, and oppressive, and therefore, hostile to the inherent right of every freeman to care for his own body and health in such way as to him seems best. . . .”104 However, the Court did not rule in Jacobson’s [hereinafter CDC, SCHOOL IMMUNIZATION REQUIREMENTS]. 95 Hodge & Gostin, supra note 7, at 834. 96 Id. at 849. 97 Id. at 850. Smallpox is a “serious, contagious, and sometimes fatal infectious disease.” Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Smallpox Disease Overview, http://www.bt.cdc.gov/agent/smallpox/overview/diseasefacts.asp (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). Unlike HPV, smallpox can be transmitted through the air. Id. Generally, direct and prolonged face-to-face contact is necessary to spread smallpox from one individual to another; however, smallpox has also been spread through the air in enclosed settings. Id. 98 Hodge & Gostin, supra note 7, at 851. 99 Id. 100 KENNETH WING ET AL., PUBLIC HEALTH LAW 59 (2007). 101 197 U.S. 11 (1905). 102 See WING ET AL., supra note 100, at 59. 103 Jacobson, 197 U.S. at 12. 104 Id. at 26. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 517 favor and decided that “[t]he safety and health of the people of [the state] are, in the first instance, for [the state] to guard and protect.”105 The Jacobson case “upholds the constitutional validity of the state’s curtailment of individual liberty in the interests of public health.”106 Notably, the Supreme Court in Jacobson recognized the limits of a state’s power and imposed certain criteria that must be met when requiring vaccinations.107 First, there must be a public health necessity.108 The state cannot exercise its power in “an arbitrary, unreasonable manner”109 and may not go “beyond what was reasonably required for the safety of the public.”110 Second, there must be a reasonable relationship between the intervention and the objective.111 The methods employed by the state must have a “real or substantial relation to the protection of the public health and the public safety”112 and cannot be “a plain, palpable invasion of rights secured by the fundamental law.”113 Third, the law cannot be “wholly disproportionate to the expected benefit.”114 The state may not use its police powers to 115 create regulations that are “arbitrary and oppressive.” Fourth, the law may not require that an adult who is not “a fit subject of 105 Id. at 38. WING ET AL., supra note 100, at 59. 107 Id. at 62. 108 Jacobson, 197 U.S. at 28. The court in In re Christine M., a 1992 New York case, declined to require inoculation of the child against smallpox due to the fact that “the urgency previously created by the [measles] epidemic or outbreak” had decreased. In re Christine M., 595 N.Y.S.2d 606, 618 (N.Y. Fam. Ct. 1992). 109 Jacobson, 197 U.S. at 28. 110 Id. 111 See id. at 28; see also GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 127 (analyzing the approach of the Jacobson Court in its adoption of the means/ends test which necessitates “a reasonable relationship between the public health intervention and the achievement of a legitimate public health objective.”). 112 Jacobson, 197 U.S. at 31. 113 Id. 114 GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 127. 115 Jacobson, 197 U.S. at 38. 106 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 518 vaccination” get vaccinated.116 Requiring vaccination that would impair one’s health “would be cruel and inhuman in the last degree.”117 Finally, although “[t]he facts in Jacobson did not require the Supreme Court to enunciate a standard of fairness under the Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment[,]”118 the federal courts had already developed a standard of fairness in an earlier case, Jew Ho v. Williamson.119 Therefore, “while Jacobson stands firmly for the proposition that police powers authorize states to compel vaccination for the public good,”120 the state may only require its inhabitants to be vaccinated when it was “necessary for the public health or the public safety.”121 Although there have been many objections to mandatory vaccinations, “[t]he early successes of school vaccination laws against most political, legal, and social challenges helped lay the 122 Since the foundation for modern immunization statutes.” introduction of smallpox vaccination laws, statutes have continuously added new vaccines to the mandatory school vaccination lists.123 The criteria set forward in Jacobson provide 116 Id. at 39. Id. at 38–39. 118 GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 128. 119 Id. In Jew Ho v. Williamson, 103 F. 10 (N.D. Cal. 1900), the court struck down a quarantine that was made to operate exclusively against the Chinese community in San Francisco. Id. at 26. In striking down the quarantine, the federal district court said it was “unreasonable, unjust, and oppressive, . . . and . . . it [was] discriminating in its character. . . .” Id. 120 Hodge & Gostin, supra note 7, at 857. 121 Jacobson v. Massachusetts, 197 U.S. 11, 27 (1905). 122 Hodge & Gostin, supra note 7, at 867. 123 Although state laws differ, most states require immunizations such as: Diphtheria, Tetanus, and acellular Pertussis (DTaP), Hepatitis A, Hepatitis B, Haemophilus influenzae Type b, Measles, Mumps, and Rubella (MMR), and Polio for school age children. See CDC, SCHOOL IMMUNIZATION REQUIREMENTS, supra note 94. In October 2008, New Jersey became the first state to mandate flu shots for children from 6 months to 5 years old who attend day care or preschool. Ridgely Ochs, NJ Flu Shot Mandate Sparks Protest, NEWSDAY, Oct. 17, 2008, at A2. This requirement resulted in various protests and “freedom of choice rall[ies]” by parents and other 117 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 519 the guidelines for the introduction of these new vaccination laws.124 B. The Recent Debate Concerning School Vaccination Requirements and the Use of Exemptions CDC officials estimate that “over time [the country’s vaccination] program has prevented about 14 million cases of vaccine-preventable diseases and 33,000 premature deaths.”125 Incidences of vaccine-preventable disease are near historical lows.126 Childhood illnesses for which there are now vaccines, such as measles, pertussis, mumps, rubella, diphtheria, tetanus and polio, “once accounted for a substantial proportion of child morbidity and mortality.”127 Yet, since the development of vaccines, the incidence of these illnesses has “significantly declined.”128 However, although most infants are vaccinated, many under-immunized children remain, potentially causing disease outbreaks.129 Parents and guardians who object to vaccinating their children often take advantage of vaccination law exemptions.130 These exemptions have been growing at a “disturbing” rate.131 activists. Id. 124 See WING ET AL., supra note 100, at 59. 125 Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Press Briefing Transcripts, http://www.cdc.gov/media/transcripts/2008/t080905.htm (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). 126 Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Vaccines & Immunizations, http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/default.htm (last visited Sept. 30, 2009). 127 Hodge & Gostin, supra note 7, at 875. 128 Id. 129 Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Vaccines & Preventable Diseases, http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/vpd-vac/default.htm (last visited Sept. 30, 2009). 130 Jennifer Steinhauer & Gardiner Harris, Rising Public Health Risk Seen As More Parents Reject Vaccines, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 21, 2008, at A1. 131 Id. For example, in California, more than 10,000 kindergartners started school in fall 2008 with vaccine exemptions, up from about 8,300 in fall 2007. Lin & Poindexter, supra note 2. “In 1997, when enrollment was SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 520 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY All fifty states have medical exemptions to vaccine requirements, and forty-eight states have religious exemptions.132 In addition, twenty-one states allow parents to exempt their children for personal reasons, sometimes related to an unproven concern that vaccines are linked to autism.133 According to Saad B. Omer, an assistant scientist at the Johns Hopkins Bloomberg School of Public Health, “[i]n 1991, less than 1 percent of children in the states with personal-belief exemptions went without vaccines based on the exemption; by 2004, the most recent year for which data are available, the percentage had increased to 2.54 percent.”134 Dr. Omer and other vaccine experts have discovered that “the easier it is to get an exemption . . . the more people opt for them.”135 There are also differences in immunization coverage within states.136 As a result of the use of exemptions, “[t]here tend to be geographic clusters of ‘exempters’ in certain counties or even neighborhoods or schools.”137 This may cause individuals who are part of an unvaccinated cluster to infect a broad community, higher, the number of exempted kindergartners was 4,318.” Id. 132 Offit, supra note 8. Although state requirements vary for what is necessary to prove a medical or religious exemption, Virginia’s statute grants a medical exemption if “[t]he parent or guardian presents a statement from a physician licensed to practice medicine in Virginia, or a licensed nurse practitioner, that states that the physical condition of the child is such that the administration of one of more of the required immunizing agents would be detrimental to the health of the child.” VA. CODE ANN. § 32.1–46(D)(2) (West 2008). A religious exemption may be granted in Virginia if “[t]he parent or guardian of the child objects thereto on the grounds that the administration of immunizing agents conflicts with his religious tenets or practices, unless an emergency or epidemic of disease has been declared by the Board.” Id. at § 32.1–46(D)(1). 133 See Bloomberg News, supra note 12. 134 Steinhauer & Harris, supra note 130, at A1. 135 Id. 136 Id. 137 Id. “[E]xemption rates of 15 percent to 18 percent have been found in Ashland, Ore[gon], and Vashon, Wash[ington]. In California, where the statewide rate is about 1.5 percent, some counties were as high as 10 percent to 19 percent of kindergartners.” Id. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 521 which includes people who have been inoculated.138 The increased use of philosophical objections to mandatory vaccine statutes is largely due to concerns that vaccinations are linked to autism.139 Even though “[t]he American Academy of Pediatrics, the CDC, the World Health Organization and the Institute of Medicine all agree that there’s probably no relationship between autism and vaccines,”140 concern among parents remains.141 The suspicion that there exists a link between vaccines and autism is partly due to the fact that parents are “bombarded with” information on the Internet, “making it tough to separate good science from bad.”142 This information can frequently “take 138 Id. See Alice Park, How Safe Are Vaccines?, TIME, June 2, 2008, at 36. Although the autism issue has been driving the debate over vaccine safety, parents also object to the mandatory nature of the shots and the fact that certain illnesses, which kids are being inoculated against, are rarely seen anymore. Id. There tend to be two separate issues concerning vaccines and autism. Martin F. Downs, Autism-Vaccine Link: Evidence Doesn’t Dispel Doubts, WEBMD, Mar. 31, 2008, http://www.webmd.com/brain/autism/ searching-for-answers/vaccines-autism. One issue arises from objections to the MMR vaccine, and the other issue is regarding thimerosal, “which contains a form of mercury that has been suspected of causing autism and has recently been removed from most vaccines.” Id. 140 Id. In February 2009, a panel of court-appointed experts “denied compensation for three families who claimed thimerosal-containing vaccine combinations caused their children’s autism.” Christina Hernandez & Delthia Ricks, Vaccine-Autism Link Not Seen, NEWSDAY, Feb. 13, 2009, at A08. These three “test” cases are among more than 4,800 families nationwide who are part of the Omnibus Autism Proceedings before the U.S. Court of Federal Claims in Washington D.C. Id. The experts found that the families failed to demonstrate that “thimerosol-containing vaccines can contribute to causing immune dysfunction, or that the MMR vaccine can contribute to causing [autism].” Id. 141 See supra text accompanying note 19. 142 Downs, supra note 139. The battle over vaccine safety has also been present in the tabloids and on television. Lin & Poindexter, supra note 2. Actress Jenny McCarthy, whose son was diagnosed as autistic, “has been outspoken in her beliefs that children are given too many vaccines too soon.” Id. 139 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 522 a life of its own online.”143 Some parents who have withheld vaccinations from their children said they did so after hearing about possible side-effects in the media, online and through other parents.144 Lee Sanders, MD, MPH, associate professor of pediatrics at the University of Miami Miller School of Medicine, explains that “[i]n the absence of any answers from the scientific community, any scintilla of suggestion is going to get magnified by the social process of talking it out.”145 Further, in May 2008, the U.S. government acknowledged that a 9-year-old Georgia girl with a preexisting cellular disease received inoculations when she was an infant, which “significantly aggravated” the condition, resulting in a brain disorder with autism-like symptoms.146 Even though the CDC states that there is likely no relationship between vaccines and autism,147 confused parents continue to opt out of vaccines altogether.148 Still, autism concerns are not the only reason parents are increasingly opting out of vaccinations for their children. Parents “object to the mandatory nature of the shots—and the fact that their child’s access to education hinges on compliance with the immunization regulations.”149 In addition, others consider certain “tame” diseases to be innocuous “rite[s] of passage” for children.150 Individuals may also “overestimate the frequency of rare risks,” such as adverse events following vaccination, or “underestimate the frequency of common risks,” such as the 143 Downs, supra note 139. Lin & Poindexter, supra note 2. 145 Downs, supra note 139. 146 Park, supra note 139. 147 CDC, Topics Related to Autism, supra note 18. 148 Park, supra note 139. 149 Id. 150 Sean Coletti, Taking Account of Partial Exemptors in Vaccination Law, Policy, and Practice, 36 CONN. L. REV. 1341, 1359 (2004). To illustrate, some parents purposefully expose their children to chicken pox: “[s]ome parents even have ‘chicken pox parties’—when one child comes down with the chicken pox, parents from all over the neighborhood bring their children to catch the disease and start the immunity process ‘naturally.’” Id. 144 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 523 devastating effects of disease.151 This distortion may be due to the fact that while one can easily remember recent adverse reactions to vaccinations, it is difficult to remember adverse effects of diseases, such as smallpox and polio, that were largely eliminated decades ago.152 Regardless of the reasons behind the increased use of philosophical exemptions, this trend could cause disease outbreaks.153 III. HPV VACCINATION A. State Legislative Activities The Advisory Committee on Immunization Practices (“ACIP”), whose members provide advice on the control of 154 vaccine-preventable diseases, began to recommend the HPV vaccination for girls between the ages eleven and twelve in June 2006.155 This recommendation created a flood of state legislative activity regarding whether or not vaccinations should be required for these girls.156 Michigan was the first state to introduce legislation in September 2006, requiring the HPV vaccine for girls entering sixth grade.157 The bill, however, was not enacted.158 Similarly, Ohio’s legislation in late 2006 requiring the vaccine also failed due to the controversial nature of the vaccine.159 As of September 2009, “[l]egislators in at least 41 states and D.C. have introduced legislation to require, fund or educate the public 151 Id. at 1369. Id. 153 See CDC, Vaccines & Preventable Diseases, supra note 129. 154 CDC, Advisory Committee on Immunization Practices, supra note 31. 155 MARKOWITZ ET AL., supra note 50, at 16. 156 See NCSL, HPV Vaccine, supra note 35. Although most state legislatures decide the issues related to school vaccination requirements, some state legislatures have granted regulatory bodies such as the Health Department the power to require vaccines. Id. 157 NCSL, HPV Vaccine, supra note 35. 158 Id. 159 Id. 152 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 524 about the HPV Vaccine and at least 19 states have enacted this legislation.”160 Iowa and Illinois, for example, have passed legislation regarding public HPV education.161 Iowa’s education standards require that the health curriculum for grades seven through twelve “shall include age-appropriate and research-based information regarding the characteristics of sexually transmitted diseases, including HPV and the availability of a vaccine to prevent HPV.”162 In Illinois, the Communicable Disease Prevention Act requires that “the Department of Health must provide all female students who are entering the sixth grade and their parents or legal guardians written information about the link between human papillomavirus (HPV) and cervical cancer and the availability of a HPV vaccine.”163 Illinois has also introduced legislation requiring funding of the vaccine: “the Department of Public Health shall establish and administer a program, commencing no later than July 1, 2011, under which any eligible individual shall, upon the eligible individual’s request, receive a series of HPV vaccinations as medically indicated, at no cost to the eligible individual.”164 Even more controversial than the legislation passed to fund or educate the public about the HPV vaccine is the fact that at least twenty-four states and the District of Columbia introduced legislation to specifically mandate the HPV vaccine for school in 2007.165 Among these twenty-four states, only Virginia and D.C. have moved toward required vaccinations for sixth-grade girls.166 Both Virginia and D.C. passed laws in 2007, but “pushed back 167 their start dates to [2009] to allow more study of the vaccine.” 160 Id. See IOWA CODE § 256.11 (2008); see also 410 ILL. COMP. STAT. 315/2e(a) (2008). 162 IOWA CODE § 256.11. 163 410 ILL. COMP. STAT. 315/2e(a). 164 20 ILL. COMP. STAT. 2310/2310–617(b) (2008). 165 NCSL, HPV Vaccine, supra note 35. 166 Potter, supra note 36. 167 Id. The Virginia legislature passed a school vaccine requirement in 2007, and considered a bill that would delay that requirement, but the Senate 161 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 525 In April 2007, Virginia passed a law requiring the HPV vaccine for females where the first dose must be administered before the child entered the sixth grade.168 The act lists the HPV vaccination requirement directly after the previously mandated vaccines in the state, including the tetanus toxoid, measles, mumps, rubella and polio vaccines.169 However, the law makes a special exception for the HPV vaccine: [b]ecause the human papillomavirus is not communicable in a school setting, a parent or guardian, at the parent’s or guardian’s sole discretion, may elect for the parent’s or guardian’s child not to receive the human papillomavirus vaccine, after having reviewed materials describing the link between the human papillomavirus and cervical cancer approved for such use by the Board.170 Thus, parents or guardians are not required to vaccinate their child against HPV so long as they read the relevant materials.171 The District of Columbia also enacted a bill mandating HPV vaccination for female sixth-graders within the District.172 This 173 requirement took effect at the start of the 2009 school year. Similar to the exemptions offered for the other mandatory vaccines, the statute offers both a medical exemption and a religious exemption to the HPV vaccination requirement.174 However, due to the vast differences between the HPV vaccination and previously mandated vaccines, the law allows Committee declined to take action on the bill. NCSL, HPV Vaccine, supra note 35; S. 722, 2008 Session (Va. 2008). 168 VA. CODE ANN. § 32.1–46(A)(12) (West 2008). 169 See id. at § 32.1–46(A). 170 Id. at § 32.1–46(D)(3). 171 See id. Female students are asked to bring in documentation if they got the vaccine. Potter, supra note 36. If they do not bring documentation, officials assume parents chose not to get the vaccination. Id. 172 D.C. CODE § 7–1651.04(b)(1) (2001). 173 Id. 174 Id. at § 7–1651.04(b)(1)(B)(i)–(ii); see also National Vaccine Information Center, State Vaccine Requirements, http://www.nvic.org/ Vaccine-Laws/state-vaccine-requirements.aspx (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 526 for an extremely broad opt-out provision.175 The statute states that a child is exempted from the HPV vaccine requirement if “[t]he parent or legal guardian, in his or her discretion, has elected to opt out of the HPV vaccination program, for any reason, by signing a form . . . that states the parent or legal guardian has been informed of the HPV vaccination requirement and has elected not to participate.”176 In addition to the broad opt-out option, the statute “[r]equires all communications from the Department of Health on the HPV vaccination program to prominently feature information pertaining to the ability of parents or guardians to opt out of the program.”177 This, combined with the mere requirement of signing a form, indicates a strong effort to advertise the voluntary nature of the HPV vaccination. Thus, although both Virginia and D.C. now require HPV vaccinations for sixth-grade girls, the broad opt-out provisions make the vaccine “more of a suggestion than a mandate.”178 B. Objections to Mandating the HPV Vaccine 1. The HPV Vaccine Differs from Traditional Infectious Disease Vaccines Since Jacobson, courts have continued to rule that states can mandate vaccination of their citizens.179 Yet, in these cases, the vaccine was used to combat an airborne disease, such as 175 See D.C. CODE § 7–1651.04(b)(1)(B)(iii). Id. If the female students haven’t either gotten the shot or turned in a form saying their parents opted out, the “girls will be held out of classes.” Potter, supra note 36. 177 D.C. CODE § 7-1651.04(a)(2). 178 Potter, supra note 36. 179 In Zucht v. King, the United States Supreme Court upheld a local mandate for vaccination as a prerequisite for public school attendance. Zucht v. King, 260 U.S. 174, 176–77 (1922). State supreme courts have also upheld school vaccination requirements. See, e.g., People ex rel. Hill v. Bd. of Educ., 195 N.W. 95, 99 (Mich. 1923). 176 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 527 smallpox.180 HPV is different from other types of diseases which mandatory vaccines are designed to protect. Joseph Zanga, a professor of pediatrics, summed it up as follows: If a kid with measles is sitting in a classroom, he or she is going to infect many other classmates. A kid with HPV infects no one other than one she might have sex with . . . . We’re not protecting the public health in the same way that we protect public health when we require measles vaccine.181 With mandatory vaccinations, the state’s interest is “in protecting the public against diseases that frequently occur in school-based epidemics or threaten school attendance when an epidemic manifests. . . .”182 The HPV vaccine, on the other hand, is a sexually-transmitted disease that will not spread in a conventional school setting.183 2. The Vaccine Does Not Protect Against All Types of HPV That Cause Cancer In the United States, cervical cancer screening has reduced the number of cervical cancer cases.184 Even with the introduction of the HPV vaccination, cervical cancer screening will still be necessary because the vaccine does not protect 180 See, e.g., Hill, 195 N.W. at 99. While “[t]he driving force behind compulsory vaccination laws was a series of outbreaks of smallpox,” the existence of “measles in schools in the 1960s and 1970s” prompted modern immunization statutes. GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 379. 181 Susan Levine & Hamil R. Harris, Wave of Support for HPV Vaccination of Girls; D.C., Md., Va. Proposals Part of National Effort to Prevent Cervical Cancer, WASH. POST, Jan. 12, 2007, at B01. 182 Lane Wood, A Young Vaccine For Young Girls: Should the Human Papillomavirus Vaccination Be Mandatory For Public School Attendance?, 20 NO. 5 HEALTH LAW. 30, 33 (2008). 183 See CDC, Genital HPV, supra note 49. 184 American Cancer Society, supra note 62. Mostly due to the increased use of the Pap test, the cervical cancer death rate declined by seventy-four percent between 1955 and 1992. Id. “The death rate from cervical cancer continues to decline by nearly 4% a year.” Id. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 528 against all types of HPV that cause cancer.185 In addition, women who are vaccinated will still need cervical cancer screening because some women may not get all required doses of the vaccine, and because women may have already acquired a vaccine HPV type, preventing them from obtaining the vaccine’s full benefits.186 Indeed, some doctors and parents worry that blanket immunizations could create a false sense of security causing women to neglect regular screening,187 which might actually raise cervical cancer rates.188 Further, “even doctors who helped devise the vaccine point out that Pap screening may be more effective in cutting cervical cancer rates.”189 These doctors note that vaccinating every single twelve-year-old “should reduce by half the number of cervical cancers in the next 35 years,” whereas Pap screening would reduce the incidence of cervical cancer by nearly seventy-five percent.190 Thus, given the existence of the screening measures already available, mandating the HPV vaccination is an unnecessary step. 3. HPV Is Sexually Transmitted The HPV vaccine is different from most other vaccines, in that it protects against a disease which is sexually transmitted.191 Thus, one concern is that required vaccinations will promote premarital sex and risky sexual behavior.192 Janet Gilsdorf, Director of Pediatric Infectious Diseases and Immunology at the University of Michigan C.S. Mott Children’s Hospital, says that 185 MARKOWITZ ET AL., supra note 50, at 17. The vaccine protects against four types of HPV, including two that cause about 70% of cervical cancer. Id. 186 CDC, Questions & Answers for the Public, supra note 41. 187 Marsa, supra note 38. 188 Id. 189 Id. 190 Id. (quoting Dr. Diane Harper, Director of the Gynecological Cancer Prevention Research Group at Dartmouth Medical School in Hanover, N.H.). 191 See CDC, Genital HPV, supra note 49. 192 Vamos et al., supra note 38. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 529 “[t]he reality is, many children get shots and they don’t ask what they’re for.”193 Therefore, the HPV vaccination does not need to result in “a major parent-child discussion about sex.”194 Yet, another view is that this lack of openness may be inconsistent with the goal of preventing HPV and cervical cancer and that education is a key to preventing the disease.195 In addition, not only do parents worry that requiring the HPV vaccine for adolescent girls will encourage sexual behavior, but also that mandating the vaccine infringes “on the decisionmaking powers of parents . . . regarding what is acceptable medical and sexual behavior.”196 4. The HPV Vaccine Is Still New—Studies Are Inconclusive Others object to the vaccine’s mandatory use because “there are too many unknowns.”197 During testing, only 1184 of the 25,000 patients in the clinical trial were preteen girls,198 the age group that is targeted in proposed, as well as approved, legislation.199 The co-founder of the National Vaccine Information Center remarked that “that’s a thin base of testing upon which to make a vaccine mandatory.”200 Further, it is not yet known how long the immunity will last, or whether eliminating some strains of cancer-causing virus will decrease 193 Levine & Harris, supra note 181. Id. 195 See CDC, Genital HPV, supra note 49. 196 Vamos et al., supra note 38, at 304. 197 Id. See, e.g., Marsa, supra note 38 (Sandra Levy has “serious reservations” about having her eleven-year-old daughter inoculated with the HPV vaccine since “we really don’t know if it’s 100% safe.”). 198 Vamos et al., supra note 38, at 305. 199 Virginia’s statute requires that “[t]he first dose shall be administered before the child enters the sixth grade.” VA. CODE ANN. § 32.1–46(a)(12) (West 2008). Similarly, the District of Columbia.’s statute requires parents of females “enrolling in grade 6 for the first time” to submit vaccination certification. D.C. CODE § 7–1651.04(b)(1) (2008). 200 Vamos et al., supra note 38, at 305. 194 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 530 the body’s natural immunity to other strains of the virus.201 In addition, although there have not been many serious adverse reactions to the vaccine,202 it is likely that “all possible side effects of the vaccine have not been determined.”203 Moreover, the known adverse effects such as Guillain-Barré Syndrome (GBS) and blood clots are “a sobering reminder that rare adverse events may surface as the vaccine is administered to millions of girls and young women.”204 Because of these medical unknowns, “Gardasil’s side effects have made some pediatricians more reluctant to recommend it for their youngest patients.”205 As one research associate at Judicial Watch stated, “It’s hard to say right now how effective [the vaccination] is. Making it mandatory is using the U.S. as a public health experiment.”206 5. The Consequences of HPV Are Not Sufficient To Mandate Vaccination for School Entry Although the states are advised by the CDC regarding which vaccines should be required, “states should mandate vaccines primarily for diseases that are highly contagious, cause significant morbidity and mortality, and pose a major health threat to students, teachers, or the community.”207 Many of the previously mandated vaccinations were required in order to protect children from devastating diseases.208 For example, 201 Elisabeth Rosenthal, Researchers Question Wide Use of HPV Vaccine, N.Y. TIMES, Aug. 20, 2008, http://www.nytimes.com/2008/08/21/health/ 21vaccine.html. 202 See supra Part I.B. 203 Vamos et al., supra note 38, at 305. 204 Javitt et al., supra note 42, at 387. 205 Susan Todd, Merck Pressing for OK to Market Gardasil for Males, THE STAR-LEDGER, Jan. 12, 2009. 206 Victoria Stagg Elliott, HPV Vaccine Talk Shifts From Fanfare to Fear, AM. MED. NEWS, Sept. 15, 2008. 207 GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 380. 208 See Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, What Would Happen If We Stopped Vaccinations?, http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/vac-gen/ SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 531 before the polio vaccine was available, 13,000 to 20,000 cases of paralytic polio were reported annually in the United States leaving children “in braces, crutches, wheelchairs, and iron lungs.”209 In the years before the Hib meningitis vaccine was available, the disease killed 600 children per year and left many survivors with deafness, seizures, or mental retardation.210 Diphtheria was a major cause of illness and death for children in the U.S. before a diphtheria vaccine was created.211 In addition, from 1964 through 1965, before the rubella immunization was routinely used, an epidemic of rubella resulted in an estimated 20,000 infants born with congenital rubella syndrome, of which 11,600 were deaf, 3,580 were blind and 1,800 were mentally retarded.212 Unlike these diseases, HPV-induced cervical cancer is a slow process that generally takes many years, and, therefore, does not affect children.213 Further, most of the time, HPV goes away on its own,214 and “few women who have HPV get cervical cancer.”215 Thus, many of the reasons that justified mandating previous vaccinations do not exist with respect to the HPV vaccination.216 whatifstop.htm (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). 209 Id. 210 Id. 211 Id. 212 Id. 213 See Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Common Questions About HPV and Cancer, http://www.cdc.gov/STD/HPV/common-questions. htm (last visited Sept. 25, 2009) [hereinafter CDC, Common Questions]. 214 CDC, Genital HPV, supra note 49. 215 CDC, Common Questions, supra note 213. “Studies suggest that whether a woman develops cervical cancer depends on a variety of factors acting together with high-risk HPVs. The factors that may increase the risk of cervical cancer in women with HPV infection include smoking and having many children.” NCI, HPV and Cancer, supra note 54. 216 See GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 380. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 532 6. Mandating the HPV Vaccine Is Inconsistent with Jacobson Unlike previously mandated vaccinations, requiring the HPV vaccination would not fit within the principles articulated in Jacobson.217 First, since HPV is passed on through sexual contact,218 it cannot be transmitted in a classroom setting from student to student.219 Therefore, unlike the smallpox vaccine in Jacobson, the HPV vaccine is not “necessary for the public health or the public safety.”220 The decision to mandate vaccination in Jacobson occurred “in the midst of a smallpox epidemic when there was no other less coercive means available to staunch the outbreak. . . . vaccination was a medical necessity to combat the disease.”221 Conversely, mandating the HPV vaccination is not a public health necessity because individuals can protect themselves through disease screening, safe sex and abstinence.222 Although like HPV, hepatitis B is passed on through sexual contact, and tetanus cannot be transmitted in a classroom setting, these diseases differ from HPV in that they still fall within the “public health necessity” category.223 For example, although hepatitis B may be transmitted sexually, it may also be communicated in other manners.224 Hepatitis B is spread when blood, semen, or other body fluid infected with the hepatitis B virus enters the body of a person who is not infected.225 People can become infected with the virus while sharing needles, 217 See supra Part II.A.1. CDC, Genital HPV, supra note 49. 219 Id. 220 See Jacobson v. Massachusetts, 197 U.S. 11 (1905). 221 Note, Toward a Twenty-First-Century, 121 HARV. L. REV. 1820, 1820 (2008). 222 Id. 223 See Jacobson, 127 U.S. at 28. 224 Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Hepatitis B FAQs for the Public, http://www.cdc.gov/hepatitis/B/bFAQ.htm (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). 225 Id. 218 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 533 syringes, or other drug-injection equipment, sharing items such as razors or toothbrushes with an infected person, or by direct contact with the blood or open sores of an infected person.226 In 2002, an Arkansas district court upheld the decision by the Arkansas legislature that required all children entering daycare, elementary and middle schools to receive the hepatitis B vaccine.227 While comparing the situation to Jacobson, the court stated: Hepatitis B may not be airborne like smallpox; however, this is not the only factor by which a disease could be judged dangerous. Hepatitis B is spread by bodily fluids; the virus is ‘fairly [hearty] and can survive on surfaces, door knobs, et cetera, for up to a month.’ . . . Immunization of school children against Hepatitis B has a real and substantial relation to the protection of the public health and the public safety. The Court therefore finds that requiring schoolchildren to be immunized against Hepatitis B is a reasonable exercise of the State’s police power and is constitutionally permissible.228 Further, although tetanus is not contagious, it is not necessarily preventable. “[G]iven [children’s] propensity to both play in the dirt and get scratches,”229 tetanus may easily be obtained in a school setting. Unlike many parents’ reaction to the HPV vaccine, parents are “very accepting of the Tetanus vaccine,”230 both because the disease is not necessarily always preventable and “because of the clear and obvious danger that their child may step barefooted on a nail or do some other dangerous activity.”231 HPV, on the other hand, is preventable— 232 by refraining from sexual activity. Second, mandating the HPV vaccination does not fit within 226 227 228 229 230 231 232 Id. Boone v. Boozman, 217 F. Supp. 2d 938, 954 (E.D. Ark. 2002). Id. Javitt et al., supra note 42, at 389. Coletti, supra note 150, at 1368. Id. CDC, Genital HPV, supra note 49. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 534 the Jacobson principle that there must be a “reasonable relationship between the public health intervention and the achievement of a legitimate public health objective.”233 Previously mandated vaccinations meet the “reasonable relationship” requirement because school-aged children are most at risk of contracting infectious diseases while in school.234 Moreover, “[a]ll children who attend school are equally at risk of both transmitting and contracting the diseases.”235 On the other hand, since HPV is sexually transmitted, exposure to the disease is not directly related to attending school.236 In addition, not all children are at equal risk of getting HPV since “[t]hose who abstain from sexual conduct are not at risk for transmitting or contracting HPV.”237 Further, arguably it is not “reasonable” to mandate the HPV vaccine at this point given the limited amount of testing.238 Third, requiring the HPV vaccine for adolescent females could be considered “disproportionate to the expected benefit.”239 This is not only due to the relatively low incidence of cervical cancer in the United States compared with the rest of the world,240 but also because the HPV vaccine only protects against four of the strains of HPV.241 Further, since the “overall prevalence of HPV types associated with cervical cancer is relatively low (3.4%),”242 mandating the vaccine for all girls may be viewed as “disproportionate.”243 233 GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 127. Javitt et al., supra note 42, at 389. 235 Id. 236 Id. 237 Id. 238 See supra Part III.B.4. 239 GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 127. 240 See National Cervical Cancer Coalition, http://www.nccc-online.org/ (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). 241 NCI, HPV and Cancer, supra note 54. 242 Lawrence O. Gostin & Catherine D. DeAngelis, Mandatory HPV Vaccination: Public Health vs. Private Wealth, 297 JAMA 1921, 1921 (2007). 243 See GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 127. 234 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 535 Finally, mandating the HPV vaccine may not withstand a fairness analysis under the Equal Protection Clause since it is currently only administered to females.244 Under the heightened scrutiny that is required for laws making sex-based distinctions, the state would have to “justify its decision to burden females with the risks of vaccination, and not males, even though males also contribute to HPV transmission.”245 In October 2009, the Food and Drug Administration approved the use of Gardasil in boys and men ages nine to twenty-six to protect them from genital warts; however, the ACIP did not encourage “its routine use in boys, as it has recommended for girls.”246 The group “questioned whether vaccinating boys was a cost-effective way to protect their future sexual partners against cervical and other types of cancer caused by . . . HPV.”247 C. The Possible Effects of Mandatory HPV Vaccination Laws Many parents and guardians are currently choosing to take advantage of exemptions to prevent their child from receiving certain vaccinations.248 Due to the availability of exemptions, “nearly one-half of 1% of kids enrolled in school are unvaccinated under a medical waiver; 2% to 3% have a nonmedical one, and the numbers appear to be rising.”249 Additionally, in an effort to avoid potential conflicts,250 some 244 See GARDASIL PACKAGE INSERT, supra note 68. Javitt et al., supra note 42, at 392. 246 Natasha Singer, Vaccine Against Virus in Girls May Be Given to Boys, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 22, 2009, at A25. 247 Id. Although males cannot contract cervical cancer, they can become infected with HPV and transmit the virus to others. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, HPV and Men Fact Sheet, http://www.cdc.gov/ STD/HPV/STDFact-HPV-and-men.htm (last visited Sept. 25, 2009). Most men who get HPV do not develop any symptoms; however, it can cause health problems, such as genital warts, anal or penile cancer. Id. 248 See Park, supra note 139. 249 Id. 250 Health officials are beginning “to take a harder line with parents who submit vaccine exemptions for nonmedical reasons.” Id. In November 2007, 245 SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 536 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY parents are choosing to “homeschool their kids so they won’t be forced to vaccinate them” with certain vaccines, such as the MMR vaccine.251 If states follow Virginia’s or D.C.’s lead and mandate the HPV vaccine for girls entering the sixth grade, it is likely that even more parents will opt out of the HPV vaccine for their children.252 Parents and guardians will object to the HPV vaccine for all of the same reasons that they object to vaccines in general, such as concerns regarding autism and the mandatory nature of the shots.253 However, due to the nature of HPV and the HPV vaccine, the vaccine presents additional worries.254 Since the HPV vaccine is not a public health necessity in the same way that other mandated vaccines are,255 “[i]t is this qualitative difference between the HPV vaccine and more traditional vaccines that resonated with the public and with state lawmakers in seeking broad exemptions to mandatory vaccination.”256 Virginia’s statute allows parents to choose not to have their daughter vaccinated as long as they review “materials describing the link between the human papillomavirus and cervical cancer approved for such use by the Board.”257 This makes it relatively 258 simple for parents to opt out of vaccinating their child. officials in Maryland “threatened to take parents to court for truancy violations if their kids did not get all their shots.” Id. On Long Island, parents are called in for “‘sincerity’ interviews with school officials . . . to determine how genuinely the vaccines conflict with religious convictions.” Id. 251 Id. 252 See supra text accompanying note 41. There is also a risk of “parental rejection of the vaccine because it is perceived as coercive.” Javitt et al., supra note 42, at 390. 253 Park, supra note 139. 254 See supra Part III.B. 255 Note, Toward a Twenty-First-Century, supra note 221, at 1838. 256 Id. at 1839. 257 VA. CODE ANN. § 32.1–46(D)(3) (West 2008). 258 The Virginia statute also allows for medical exemptions if [t]he parent or guardian presents a statement from a physician licensed to practice medicine in Virginia, or a licensed nurse practitioner, that states that the physical condition of the child is such SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 537 Although the statute differentiates the HPV vaccine by stating that it “is not communicable in a school setting,”259 the ease in which a parent can exercise this opt out right could encourage parents to then seek exemptions to other previously mandated vaccines which protect against diseases that are communicable in a school setting. The HPV vaccine is dissimilar to previously mandated vaccines,260 which is why it is expected to draw additional scrutiny by parents.261 Further, the ability to opt out of the HPV vaccine is not masked. In fact, the District of Columbia’s legislation specifically calls for the advertisement of the opt-out provision of the HPV vaccination: all “communications from the Department of Health on the HPV vaccination program” must “prominently feature information pertaining to the ability of parents or guardians to opt out of the program.”262 Thus, many parents will likely exercise their right to opt-out of the HPV vaccination for their daughters.263 The broad opt-out provision for the HPV vaccine may bring some parents and guardians, who otherwise might not have, to look into the availability of vaccine exemptions in their state for other vaccines. Although parents would likely use the philosophical exemption if it is available in their state, “more and more parents today are claiming religious exemptions regardless of whether the religion they belong to explicitly prohibits it.”264 Further, in states without philosophical that the administration of one or more of the required immunizing agents would be detrimental to the health of the child and for religious exemptions if “[t]he parent or guardian of the child objects thereto on the grounds that the administration of immunizing agents conflicts with his religious tenets or practices.” Id. at § 32.1–46(D)(1)–(2). 259 Id. at § 32.1–46(D)(3). 260 See supra Part III.B.1. 261 See Gardner, supra note 39; see also Marsa, supra note 38. 262 D.C. CODE § 7–1651.04 (2008). 263 See Gardner, supra note 39. 264 Coletti, supra note 150, at 1350. For example, in New Jersey, to file for a religious exemption, a parent only needs to “write a letter stating how the vaccines conflict with the family’s religious beliefs.” Jill P. Capuzzo, SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 538 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY exemptions, besides using religious or medical exemptions, parents may also send their children to parochial or private schools or home school their children, increasing alternatives for parents seeking to avoid vaccinating their children.265 In sum, introducing parents to the idea of opting out of the HPV vaccination for their daughter may encourage these parents to seek exemptions not only for the HPV vaccine, but for other previously mandated vaccines that have proved to be tremendously effective over the years. Once parents realize the ease of which they can opt out of the HPV vaccine, they may then seek to opt out of other vaccines by using exemptions. The increased use of exemptions is already a cause for concern, primarily due to recent measles and whooping cough outbreaks,266 and any additional encouragement to opt out of mandatory vaccines will only exacerbate the situation. IV. CONCLUSION From 2007 to 2008, the number of thirteen to seventeenyear-old girls who had received the first of three doses of the HPV vaccine increased from 25 to 37 percent.267 This increase occurred, despite the fact that most states have not instituted a HPV vaccine requirement for school entry.268 Therefore, this Some Parents Seek Options to Vaccine Orders, N.Y. TIMES, Dec. 23, 2007. Verification by a member of the clergy is not required. Id. Further, organizations exist to assist parents in their application. See id. For example, Barbara Flynn, a mother of two, has a Web site, www.callingtheshots.info, where she provides a sample three-page letter that parents can use when drafting their own letter. Id. 265 Capuzzo, supra note 264. 266 See Bloomberg News, supra note 12. 267 David Olmos, Third of Teen Girls Get Cancer Vaccine, NEWSDAY, Sept. 18, 2009, at A32. Rates of vaccination “varied widely among the states, from 54.4 percent in New Hampshire to 15.8 percent in Mississippi.” Id. 268 See NCSL, HPV Vaccine, supra note 35. The Virginia legislature passed a school vaccine requirement in 2007, and considered a bill that would delay that requirement, but the Senate Committee declined to take action on the bill. Id. D.C.’s bill was enacted and the requirement started at the SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM ONE STEP FORWARD, TWO STEPS BACK 539 trend supports the idea that mandatory HPV vaccination is an unnecessary measure at this point—especially when there is an increasing amount of vaccine skeptics.269 Even without a mandatory requirement, an increasing number of females are currently obtaining the HPV vaccination.270 Recently, concerns regarding a connection between autism and vaccinations have fueled the battle over vaccines,271 and as a result, parents are paying close attention to vaccine requirements and their right to decide what is best for their child.272 Indeed, the use of exemptions is increasing.273 Unfortunately, this increase in the use of exemptions has already led to an observable rise in vaccine-preventable disease,274 with major 275 outbreaks of measles and pertussis. For example, states “with easily obtained exemptions had higher non-medical exemption rates and increased incidence of pertussis.”276 As states continue to consider the contentious subject of whether or not to require girls to be vaccinated against HPV, it is imperative that the state legislatures consider not only the effect of the mandate itself, but also the effect of any opt-out provisions the legislature chooses to include. Including the HPV vaccination on the list of mandated vaccines for school-entry with broad opt-out provisions will only encourage the use of exemptions, thereby undermining our nation’s public health. The development of vaccines was one of the “great public health achievements of the twentieth century,”277 resulting in a dramatic decrease in common childhood illnesses that “once accounted for beginning of the 2009 school year. Id. 269 Steinhauer & Harris, supra note 130. 270 See Olmos, supra note 267. 271 Park, supra note 139, at 36. 272 See Steinhauer & Harris, supra note 130 (explaining that there is “an increasing number” of “vaccine skeptics” often due “to an unproven notion that vaccines are linked to autism and other disorders”). 273 See id. 274 US Measles Increase Caused by Vacc Scare, supra note 25. 275 GOSTIN, supra note 6, at 380. 276 Id. 277 Id. at 376. SOUTHARD REVISED.DOC 4/26/2010 10:03 PM JOURNAL OF LAW AND POLICY 540 a substantial proportion of child morbidity.”278 Although the approval of a vaccine against cancer-causing HPV strains is a tremendous step forward in improving our nation’s health, mandating its use will have an overall detrimental effect for it and other vaccines. Until states figure out an alternative to including broad opt-out provisions in their legislation, voluntary HPV vaccination is the best alternative. 278 Id.