The Security Dilemma in Alliance Politics
Transcription
The Security Dilemma in Alliance Politics
Trustees of Princeton University The Security Dilemma in Alliance Politics Author(s): Glenn H. Snyder Source: World Politics, Vol. 36, No. 4 (Jul., 1984), pp. 461-495 Published by: Cambridge University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2010183 . Accessed: 05/11/2014 22:57 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. . Cambridge University Press and Trustees of Princeton University are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to World Politics. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions THE SECURITY DILEMMA IN ALLIANCE POLITICS By GLENN H. SNYDER* THE SECURITY DILEMMA A CENTRAL concept in internationalrelationstheory,but stillone of the most under-studiedempirically,is that of the "securitydilemma."' The term is generallyused to denote the self-defeatingaspect of the quest for securityin an anarchic system.The theorysays that even when no state has any desire to attack others,none can be sure that others' intentionsare peaceful,or will remain so; hence each must accumulate power for defense. Since no state can know that the power accumulation of othersis defensivelymotivatedonly,each must assume that it might be intended for attack. Consequently,each party'spower incrementsare matched by the others,and all wind up with no more securitythan when the vicious cyclebegan, along withthe costsincurred in having acquired and having to maintain theirpower. States accumulate power in many ways; the most prominentmethods are by armament, territorialaggrandizement,and alliance formation. The "supergame" of internationalsecuritymay thus be divided, for analyticalpurposes, into threesubgames: the armamentsgame, the adversarygame, and thealliance game. Typically,discussionsofthe security dilemma are illustratedby the armamentsgame: the arms race is seen as the epitome of competitionfor illusorysecurity.Sometimes,at least implicitly,the securitydilemma is seen operatingin the adversarygame (competitionother than armaments),as in explanationsthat ascribe the cold war to the United States and the Soviet Union misperceivingeach other's "defensive" actions in Europe as "aggressive." Little attention has so far been paid to the securitydilemma dynamics of the alliance game. The presentessay is intendedto fillthisgap, and to explore some * I wish to thank Robert Art, David Goldfischer,Robert Jervis,Robert Osgood, Dean Pruitt,JackSnyder,and Kenneth Waltz, forhelpfulcomments;and the Woodrow Wilson InternationalCenter for Scholars and the Instituteof War and Peace Studies, Columbia University,forfinancialsupportand officespace. I The best recenttreatmentis RobertJervis, "Cooperation under the SecurityDilemma," WorldPolitics30 (JanuaryI978), i67-2 I4. The conceptof thesecuritydilemma was originated by JohnHerz, in his PoliticalRealismand PoliticalIdealism(Chicago: Universityof Chicago Press, I95I). This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 462 WORLD POLITICS interactionsbetween the alliance game and the adversarygame in multipolar and bipolar systems. ALLIANCE FORMATION THE PRIMARY IN A MULTIPOLAR ALLIANCE SYSTEM: DILEMMA The securitydilemma in the alliance game has two phases: primary and secondary.The primaryphase occurs during the processof alliance formation,the secondaryone afteralliances have formed. In a multipolarsystem(such as the one thatexisted before I945), the primaryalliance dilemma among the major states follows the logic of an N-person prisoner'sdilemma. Each state has two options: seek allies or abstain from alliances. If all states are about equally strongand are interestedonly in security,all are fairlywell offif all abstain,since each has moderate securityagainst individual others,while alliances involve various costs,such as reduced freedomof action,commitmentsto defend the interestsof others,and so forth.Alliances will form,however, for two reasons: (I) some states may not be satisfiedwith only moderate security,and theycan increaseit substantiallyby allyingifothersabstain; (2) some states,fearingthat otherswill not abstain,will ally in order to avoid isolation or to preclude the partner from allying against them. Once an alliance forms,a counter-alliancenecessarilyfollows,since there is no way of knowing thatthe firstalliance is intendedonly fordefensive purposes. The eventual resultis the divisionof the systeminto two rival coalitions. This outcome is worse than all-around abstention because each state has incurred the risks and burdens of alliance with little improvementin its security.2 Figure I portraysthe primaryalliance securitydilemma. Although it is cast in two-person form,it is understood that for player A, the other player,B, means "all otherplayers,"and vice versa. The numbers in the cells are ordinal, ranked from 4 (best) to I (worst). The first number in each cell representsA's payoff,the second B's. The logical This is, of course, an idealized model based on certain assumptionsfrom which the empirical world will deviate more or less, fromtime to time. The basic assumptionsare that: (i) no state is aggressive,but none can know the intentionsof others; (2) the states are roughlyequal in militarystrength;and (3) militarytechnologyis such that thereis no time to forma successfuldefensealliance afterwar begins. Uncertaintyabout the aims of others is inherentin structuralanarchy. If a state clearly reveals itselfas expansionist, as in the prisoners'dilemma however,thealliance thatformsagainstit is not "self-defeating" (securitydilemma) model. Or, if some statesare weaker than others,theirmotivesto ally will be differentfromthe incentivesof the prisoner'sdilemma. The thirdassumptionhas been valid since about i870. Before then (when the pace of warfare was slower), the compulsion to ally in peacetime was much weaker than suggestedby the model. Despite these qualificationsand possiblyothers,the model does capturesome essentialdynamicsof multipolaralliance formationbetween i870 and I939. 2 This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE FIGURE THE PRIMARY DILEMMA SECURITY ALLIANCE 463 I SECURITY DILEMMA B ABSTAIN ABSTAIN All-around abstention 3,3 A ALLY A's coalition forms B isolated 4,1 ALLY B's coalition forms A isolated "4 Two rival coalitions 2, 2 forall players.The outcome,two rivalcoalitions,is the second-worst allsecond-best, the best,formingan alliancewhileothersdo not,and becauseofuncertainty cannotbe obtained,primarily aroundabstention, need to guard about the intentionsof othersand the overwhelming againsttheworstoutcome,thatof isolation. This modelpredictsonlythatallianceswill form.It does notpredict risks,and costsof an who will align withwhom,or how thebenefits, alliancewillbe dividedamongitsmembers.These matterstheoretically are decidedby a processof bargainingin whichthe statescompetein Each state sharesofthealliance's"payoff." each otherattractive offering has two principalaims in the bargaining:to be in the mostpowerful These coalition,and to maximizeitsshareofthealliance'snetbenefits.3 of the statein the alliancegame. If thesewere the are the "interests" at stake,the alliancebargainingprocesswould be comonlyinterests pletelyindeterminatethatis, each statewould be equallyeligibleas theallyor theadversaryof everyotherstate. is reduced,thoughnot In therealworld,however,theindeterminacy from thealliancegame whichexistapart eliminated, byotherinterests, and which predisposestatesto align with certainothersand against 3 "Being in" the most powerfulcoalition does not necessarilymean that states join the most powerfulcoalition that is already in existence.Indeed, theywill more likelyjoin the weaker one which then becomes the most powerful as a consequence of their joining, because this gives them leverage to bargain for a maximum share of the alliance's payoff. Thus the logic of N-person game theoryis consistentwith Waltz's argumentthat states "balance" ratherthan "bandwagon." See Kenneth N. Waltz, TheoryofInternational Politics (Reading, Mass.: Addison Wesley, I979), I25-26. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 464 WORLD POLITICS others. Here we must distinguishbetween "general" and "particular" interests.General interestsstemfromtheanarchicstructureof the system and the geographic position of the state. They include, for instance,a state'sinterestin defendinga close neighbor,or in expansion to enhance its security,or even more generally,in preservinga balance of power in the system.Typical examples of general interestswould be England's traditionalinterestin preservingthe independenceof the Low Countries and in maintaininga balance of power on the Continent.Such interests are "general" because they do not involve conflictsover specificissues with specificother states,but will be defended or acted upon against all comers.Since theyare valued chieflyfortheirpower and securitycontent, I will occasionally referto them as "strategic" interests.Such general strategicinterestsintroduceonly a modest amount of determinacyinto the basic N-person model. The indeterminacyis furtherreduced by the "particular" interestsof states, which bring them into conflictor affinitywith specific other states.These conflictsand commonalitiesmay have some power content or theymay stem fromideological, ethnic,economic,or prestigevalues. The Franco-English conflictsover Egypt in the i9th centuryand the Austro-German ethnic affinityare examples. Particular conflictsor affinitiesof interestestablisha tacit patternof alignment,prior to or apart fromany overt alliance negotiations.That is, stateswill expect to be supportedin some degree by those with whom theyshare interestsand to be opposed by those with whom theyare in conflict.To illustrate:in the decade of the i870s, Germany had a serious conflictwith France over Alsace-Lorraine, but no significantconflicts with any of the other major powers. Russia had conflictswith Austria over the Balkans, and withEngland over theStraitsquestion and colonial issues fromthe Middle East to China. England was on good termswith Germany,Austria,and Italy,but was in conflictwith Russia and France over colonial issues. Italy had territorialconflictswith Austria in Europe and with France in Africa. The autocratic governmentsof Germany, Russia, and Austria stood on ideological common ground, but were ideologically antagonistictoward the three Western democracies. The alignmentsimplied by these conflictsand affinitieswere: (i) on grounds of territorialinterest: England and Austria versus Russia; England, Germany,and Italy versus France; and France and Russia versus England; (2) on ideological grounds: Germany,Austria, and Russia versus England, France, and Italy. Such conflictsand alignments of interestand ideology establish a This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 465 backgroundof relationships againstwhichtheovertalliancebargaining processtakesplace,and whichaffectthatprocessconsiderably, predisposingthe systemtowardcertainalliancesand againstothers.These relationships may foreclosesome combinations if the conflictis severe enough;in othercases,theabsenceof conflict betweensomepairsmay make them naturalallies. More likely,however,theseconflictsand affinities will narrowtherangeof indeterminacy ratherthaneliminate it. Naturalpartnersmayfailto allybecauseone of themoverestimates the other'sconflictswith thirdpartiesand triesto drive too hard a bargain,as Germanydid in negotiations withEnglandin i899 and i9oi. And naturalopponentsmaybe able toovercometheirconflicts, as France of and England did in I904. Technically,conflicts and commonalities particularinterestenterinto the bargainingprocessby reducingor increasing thetotalvalue,or "payoff," ofcertainalliances,thusreducing or increasingthe likelihoodthattheywill form.For example,a state withwhichone has a conflict will appearas a morelikelyopponentin war than otherstates;hence,an allianceagainstit will yieldgreater valuethanan alliancewithit;thelatterwouldrequirea priorsettlement of theconflict, interests. incurring costsin theformof compromised Thus, althoughan alliancebetweenFrance and Germanywas not logicallyout of the questionbetweeni870 and I9I4, it was extremely of theAlsace-Lorraine unlikely:it requireda settlement issue,a compromisethatwould have costone or bothpartiestoo muchcompared to the deals theycould negotiatewithothers.Francecould get Russia as a partner at theminorcostofswallowingsomeideologicalrepugnance, and she could get England by givingup a positionin Egyptthatwas valuableonlyforprestigereasonsand could hardlybe maintainedfor long. The choiceof alliesis also influenced bytheinternalpoliticalconfigurationsof statesapart fromthe generalideologicalpreferences just mentioned.For example,the Anglo-FrenchEntenteof I904 probably would not have occurred,and certainly would not have developedso soon intoa quasi-allianceagainstGermany,if the Radical ratherthan theImperialistwingof theBritishLiberalpartyhad been in chargeof theforeignpolicymakingpostsin theCabinet. To summarize:in a multipolarsystemthereis a generalincentiveto allywithsomeotherstateor states,followingthelogicof theN-person prisoner'sdilemma,or security dilemma,thatis generatedbythestructureof the system.Who alignswithwhom resultsfroma bargaining processthatis theoretically indeterminate. The indeterminacy is reduced, This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 466 WORLD POLITICS though not eliminated, by the prior interests,conflicts,and affinities between states and their internalpolitical make-up.4 AFTER THE ALIGNMENTS SECONDARY ALLIANCE FORM: DILEMMA Once alliances have begun to form, the alliance securitydilemma takes on a differentcharacter.That is, having already "defected" in the primarydilemma by choosing to make alliances, states move into the second phase of the alliance dilemma, in which their choices are no longer whetherto ally or not, but how firmlyto commit themselvesto the proto-partnerand how much supportto give thatpartnerin specific conflictinteractionswith the adversary.The horns of this secondary dilemma may be described by the traditionallabels "cooperate" (C) and "defect" (D), where cooperation means a stronggeneral commitment and full support in specificadversaryconflicts,and defectionmeans a weak commitmentand no supportin conflictswith the adversary.The secondary alliance dilemma may or may not be a prisoner'sdilemma. (Henceforthin thisdiscussion,the terms"alliance game" and "dilemma" will referto the secondarygame ratherthan the primaryone.) Each horn of the dilemma has both prospectivegood and prospective bad consequences; and the "goods" and "bads" foreach alternativetend to be the obverse of those of the other.In the alliance securitydilemma, the principal "bads" are "abandonment" and "entrapment,"and the principal "goods" are a reduction in the risks of being abandoned or entrapped by the ally.5 In a multipolar system,alliances are never absolutelyfirm,whatever the textof the writtenagreement;therefore,the fearof being abandoned by one's ally is ever-present.Abandonment, in general, is "defection," but it may take a varietyof specificforms: the ally may realign with the opponent; he may merelyde-align,abrogatingthe alliance contract; he may fail to make good on his explicitcommitments;or he may fail to provide supportin contingencieswhere supportis expected. (In both of the lattertwo variants,thealliance remainsintact,but theexpectations of support which underlie it are weakened.) Suspicion that the ally is 4Despite the importanceof internalpolitics,this referencewill be the only one in this essay.For reasonsof theoreticalparsimonyand space limitations,theanalysisis based entirely on what in recentlypopular academic terminologyis called the "rationalactor model," the actors being states. 5The conceptsof abandonmentand entrapmentwere firstposited,I believe,by Michael Mandelbaum, in The Nuclear Revolution:InternationalPoliticsBeforeand AfterHiroshima (New York: Cambridge UniversityPress, i98i), chap. 6. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 467 consideringrealignment maygeneratean incentiveto realignpreemptively. Entrapment means being dragged into a conflictover an ally's intereststhat one does not share, or shares only partially.The interestsof allies are generallynot identical; to the extenttheyare shared,theymay be valued in differentdegree. Entrapmentoccurs when one values the preservationof the alliance more than the cost of fightingfor the ally's interests.It is more likely to occur if the ally becomes intransigentin disputeswithopponentsbecause of his confidencein one's support.Thus, the greater one's dependence on the alliance and the strongerone's commitmentto the ally, the higher the risk of entrapment.The risk also varies with the ally's inherentdegree of recklessnessor aggressiveness. The risks of abandonment and entrapmenttend to vary inversely: reducing one tends to increase the other.Thus a "C" strategyof strong commitmentto an ally reduces the risk of abandonment by reducing his fear of abandonment; he is discouraged fromdefectingby his confidence in one's support. But this very support may encourage him to excessiveboldness in disputesor criseswith the adversary,thus exposing one to the risk of a war that one would not wish to fight.Conversely, a "D" strategyof weak or vague commitment,or a record of failingto support the ally in specificconflicts,tends to restrainthe ally and to reduce the risk of entrapment;but it also increases the risk of abandonment by castingdoubt on one's loyalty,hence devaluing the alliance for the ally. Thus, the resolutionof the alliance securitydilemma the choice of strategy requires chieflya comparisonand trade-offbetween the costs and risks of abandonment and entrapment. There are certainother"goods" and "bads" thatenterinto thealliance securitydilemma. A strategyof strong commitmentand support will have the undesired effectof reducingone's bargainingleverage over the ally.If he knows he can counton being supported,he is less influenceable. Conversely,bargainingpower over the ally is enhanced to the extenthe doubts one's commitmentbecause one can then make credible threats of nonsupport.Alliance bargaining considerationsthus tend to favor a strategyof weak or ambiguous commitment-a "D" strategyin the alliance game. (Note that the opposite is the case in the adversarygame where firmcommitmentsto defend one's intereststend to strengthen bargaining power vis-a-visthe opponent.) Another negative effectof strong commitmentis that it tends to forecloseone's own options of realignment.Despite the general com- This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 468 WORLD POLITICS pulsion to align in a multipolarsystem,statesusually want to keep their commitmentstentativeor vague as long as possible-both to preserve opportunitiesfor shiftingpartnersin case the presentone turnsout to be unsatisfactory and to maximize bargainingleverage over the current partner by showing that they have alternatives.A strategyof weak commitmenthas the desirableeffectof keeping alignmentoptionsopen. Finally,a strongcommitmentto theally tendsto solidifytheadversary alliance by increasing the degree of threat to it. A weak or tentative commitmentreduces this effectand may even weaken or divide the opposing alliance by preserving,for statesin that alliance, the apparent option of realigningwith oneself. INTERACTION BETWEEN ALLIANCE AND ADVERSARY GAMES Up to now, I have been discussing the alliance game or dilemma more or less independentlyof adversaries. But allies are dealing with theiradversariesat the same time theyare dealing with each other.The alliance and adversarygames proceed simultaneouslyand complement each other in various ways. Strategiesand tacticsin the alliance game will have directeffectsin thatgame, but also side-effects in the adversary game-and vice versa. Strategychoices in either game must therefore take account of both kinds of effects. Table I presentsa compositesecuritydilemma thatcombinesthe two games. Each of the strategypairs, I and II, shows an alliance strategy, togetherwith its complementarystrategyin the adversarygame. (The cooperative"C" strategiesand thedefecting"D" strategiesare shorthand for a wide range of empirical variationsthat cannot be explored here.) The two columns show the possible directconsequences of alliance and adversarystrategiesin their respectivegames. The column labeled "alliance game" simplysummarizes the previous discussion. The column labeled "adversary game" shows the possible "good" and "bad" effectsof either conciliationor firmnesstoward an adversarywhen one is interestedonly in maintainingthe general status quo. The securitydilemma arises from the state's uncertaintywhether its adversaryhas far-reachingexpansionistaims or, like itself,is interested essentiallyin the preservation,or limitedmodification,of the status quo. If the opponent is expansionist,a policy of firmnesspromises the desirable effectsof deterringhim and enhancing one's own reputation for resolve. However, if he is basically oriented toward the status quo, a tough stance may provoke him, increase tension,and induce an "in- This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY TABLE THE COMPOSITE SECURITY 469 DILEMMA I DILEMMA IN A MULTIPOLAR SYSTEM PossibleConsequences Strategies Alliancegame Adversary game GOODS I. I ALLIANCE 2. reduce risk of abandonment Enhance reputation forloyalty GOODS I. 2. Deter,or prevail over, adversary Enhance reputation for resolve C: Support, strengthenpcommitment ADVERSARY Reassureally, D: Stand firm. BADS Increase risk of entrapment 2. Reduce bargaining power over ally 3. Foreclose realignment option 4. Solidifyadversary's alliance I. BADS I. Provoke adversary; increasetension; insecurityspiral GOODS I. GOODS I. Resolve conflict; reduce tension Increase bargaining power over ally 3. Preserverealignment option II ALLIANCE Restrainally, reduce risk of entrapment 2. D: Withhold support, weaken commitment 4. Divide adversary's alliance BADS ADVERSARY C: Conciliate I. 2. Increase risk of abandonment Reduce reputation forloyalty BADS I. 2. Encourage adversary to stand firmer Reduce reputation forresolve securityspiral" that is, a vicious circle of "unnecessary"power competitionbecause the adversaryinterpretsone's own firmnessas aggressiveness toward him. Conversely, a conciliatorypolicy may have the desirable effectof resolving conflictand reducing tension with an essentiallynonaggressiveadversary; on the other hand, if the opponent This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 470 WORLD POLITICS has expansionistgoals, conciliationmay encourage him to make further demands in the belief that one lacks resolve.6 Strategiesin each game can have desirable or undesirableside effects in the other.In making choices,a statemust thereforecalculate the sum of directeffectsand side effects.To save space, I will discuss here only the side effectson the alliance game of strategiesin the adversarygame, and omit the obverseside effects.An adversary"D" strategyof firmness, resistance,or coercion will tend to reassure an ally who doubts one's loyalty,and reduce the risk of the ally's defectionor realignment.Opposed to this "good" are several "bads." Firmness toward the adversary increases the risk of entrapmentby the ally, as the ally becomes intransigentthroughhis confidencein one's support.Firmnessin the adversary game reducesbargainingpower over theallyin thealliance game because it reduces the credibilityof a threatto withholdsupport.A tough stance toward the adversaryalso tends to close off the option of realignment with him. Toughness will also cause the adversaryto move closer to his own allies, thus solidifyinghis alliance. 6 The adversarydilemma presentedhere is a secondarysecuritydilemma, analogous to the secondaryalliance dilemma. In both cases, the primarysecuritydilemma, which is a prisoner'sdilemma, has already been resolvedby mutual defection.That is, alliances have formedand adversaries have adopted a general posture of power/security rivalryin the "DD" cell of the primarygame, which we mightalso call the international"supergame." Once adversariesare in this cell they may be able to reduce their conflict;on the other hand, theymay sink deeper into conflictand competition.That is, having protectedthemselves against the worst,theyare now able to consider whetherthey might not improve their situationby conciliatingthe opponent-although they must also guard against exploitationof such cooperation.Whether conciliationor continued (or greater)firmnessis the betterpolicy for any state will depend on its adversary'spreferences-which the state does not know, although presumablyit knows its own. The adversarydilemma in Table I simplyassumes theextremes-the opponentis eitherstatus-quo-oriented or expansionisteven thoughhe may have mixed motivesor be expansionistin different degree in different situations.Formally speaking, adversariesplay a series of sub-games within the general contextof supergame "DD." Some of these may be prisoner'sdilemmas,but some may be othergames thatare eithermoreor less conflictualthantheprisoner'sdilemma.The dilemma for the state,then,arises fromits uncertaintyas to what game is being played, which in turnstemsfromitsuncertainty about theadversary'spreferences. Choosing the beststrategy thusrequiresan estimateof the opponent'spreferencerankingsforpossibleoutcomes.Space forbidsa discussionof the various possiblesub-games:in Table i, theyare implicitly"Stag Hunt" (when the opponent prefersthe statusquo) and a variantof "Chicken" (when the opponent is expansionistbut preferspeace over expansion by war). For a comprehensive treatment,see Glenn H. Snyder and Paul Diesing, ConflictAmong Nations (Princeton: PrincetonUniversityPress, I977), chap. 2. The secondaryadversarydilemma is similar to the dichotomybetween the axioms of deterrencetheoryand thoseof the "spiral model" as describedby RobertJervisin Perception and Misperception in International Politics(Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress, I976), chap. 3. Jervismakes the point that the choice between deterrenceand spiral-modelaxiomsbetweenfirmnessand accommodation-depends essentiallyon one's estimateof the adversary'sultimateaims. Jervisdoes not apply the term"securitydilemma" to thisbroad choice, but uses it in its traditionalsense as an explanationof why the search for securityamong status-quostatesmay be self-defeating-i.e.,as the structuralbasis of the spiral model. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 471 A "C" strategyof conciliatingthe adversarywill have the desirable side effectof restrainingthe ally, thus reducing the risk of entrapment. The ally, observing one's improving relationswith the opponent, will have less confidencethat one will stand four-squarebehind him in a crisis; consequently,he will be more cautious in his own dealings with the opponent. He may even interpretthe improved relationswith the adversary as a sign that one is consideringrealignment;he may then become more amenable in order to discourage one's defection.Conciliating the opponent also keeps open one's option of realignmentwith him, which is desirable forits own sake as well as forthe enhancement of one's bargaining leverage over the presentpartner.Accommodating an adversarymay also weaken his alliance, as his partnersbegin to doubt his loyaltyand seek alternativepartners. The most undesirable side effectof conciliatingthe adversaryis that it entails the risk of abandonment by the ally. His fear that one is contemplatingrealignmentmay induce him, not to try to discourage thisby becomingmore accommodative,as suggestedabove, but to realign preemptivelyor at least move closer to the opponent. This risk is an importantconstrainton conciliationbetween adversaries,possibly offsettingthe benefitsfromgreatercooperationin the adversarygame.7 THE DETERMINANTS OF CHOICE What determineschoices in the alliance securitydilemma? Thus far, we have suggested only a superficialanswer to this question: choice involves estimatesof, and trade-offsamong, the various benefits,costs, and riskslisted in Table I. But what determinesthe magnitude of these values and consequentlythe severityof the dilemma? Probably the most importantdeterminantis the relativedependence of the partnerson the alliance-how much theyneed each other'saidand their perceptionsof each other's dependence. Thus, the more dependent a state is, and/orthe less dependent the ally appears to be, the 7 There are some interesting analogies betweenthe dynamicsof the two games. A strategy of conciliationin the adversarygame may produce a "fallingdomino" effect:the opponent interpretsone's overtureas weakness and pushes harderon both presentand futureissues. The alliance analogue is the entrapmenteffect.As an opponentmay be emboldened if he is appeased, the ally may become more intransigentand aggressiveif he is supported.The alliance analogue to deterrenceof the opponentis restraintof the ally. Deterrenceinvolves a threatof forceagainst an adversary;restraintmay be accomplishedby threateningnot to use forcein supportof the ally. In the alliance game, strengthening one's commitmentto the ally tends to forecloseone's alternativealliance options; in the adversarygame, firming up one's commitmentagainst the opponentmay foreclosecompromisesettlementoptions. Bargainingpower over the ally is enhanced by a weak, ambiguous commitment;leverage over the adversaryis strengthenedby a firm,explicitone. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 472 WORLD POLITICS more likely it is that the costs and risksof abandonment will outweigh the costs and risks of entrapment.Dependence is compounded of (i) a state's need for assistance in war as a functionof the extent to which its militarycapability falls short of its potential adversary'scapability; (2) its partner'scapacityto supplythe assistance(the greaterthe partner's strength,the more one is dependent on him, up to the point where the combined strengthprovides sufficientsecurity);(3) the state's degree of conflictand tension with the adversary (the greater the conflictand tension,the more likely one will have to call on the partnerfor help);8 and (4) the state's realignment alternatives(the more numerous the alternatives,and the more satisfactory theyare, the less the dependence on the presentpartner).These factorswill of course change over time; some may change in opposite directions. For example, by I9I4 the increased militarystrengthof France and Russia (especially the latter) had reduced theirdependence on England, but this was partiallyoffset by theirincreased conflictwith Germany and Austria. Also, the factors are not entirelyindependent.Thus, increasedconflictwith the adversary will reduce realignmentalternativesby tending to close offthe option of realigningwith him. Another determinantis the degree of strategicinterestthat the parties have in defendingeach other.Strategicinterestis an interestin keeping the ally's power resourcesout of the opponent's hands. Analytically,this is differentfrom dependence as just defined,since it refersnot to the need foraid in case one is attacked,but to the need to block an increase in the adversary'spower. In practice,the two are closely linked since the ally's independent existence is a prerequisite to receiving his aid. Strategicinterestmight be termed"indirectdependence," and need for the ally's assistancemightbe labeled "directdependence." Most alliances in a multipolarworld involveboth kinds of dependence,but theyshould be kept separate because allies may be dependent in differentdegree on each dimension. The most importantcauses of such asymmetriesare geographical factorsand disparityof power betweenallies. The English Channel, for instance, minimized Britain's direct dependence on her continentalallies, but she was indirectlydependent on them because domination of the Continentby a single power would have neutralized the protection of the Channel. In the pre-I9I4 decade, France was directlydependent on British aid, but had little operational strategic 8 "Conflict" ofinterest; and "tension" areanalytically Conflict is incompatibility separable. willproducewar in tensionmaybe definedcrudelyas thefeltlikelihoodthattheconflict theimmediate future. A highdegreeof conflict maybe accompanied bylow tension;the oppositeis alsopossible, thoughlesslikely.The twoarelinkedherebecauseoftheirsimilar on alliancedependence. effect This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 473 interestin defending England because England could defend herself against direct attack by Germany. The effectsof power disparitymay be seen in the German-Austrianalliance of I879. Because of her relative weakness, Austria was much more dependent in a directsense on German assistance against Russia than vice versa, but Germany was indirectlydependent because of her strategicinterestin preventingAustria frombeing absorbed by Russia.9 Asymmetriesin indirectdependence chieflyaffectthe partners'relative fearsof abandonment.Thus, when one statehas a strongerstrategic interestin its partner than vice versa, the firstwill worrymore about abandonment than the second, although this differentialmay be offset if the second state is more dependent in the directsense. Differencesin strategicinteresthelp to explain why the most powerful state in an alliance often has little leverage over its partners: when the stronger state's strategicinterestis well known, it cannot crediblythreatendefectionor realignment. in the alliance agreeA thirddeterminantis the degree of explicitness ment. A vague or ambiguous agreement tends to maximize fears of abandonment; an explicit one minimizes such worries,but it does not eliminate them. Conversely,entrapmentmay be a less worrisomepossibilitywith a vague agreement since the partnerscan assert that they are not committed.The flip side of this, however, is that while states explicitlyallied may be entrapped over the partner'sintereststhat are covered in the agreement, they may find it quite easy to dissociate themselvesfrom the ally in contingenciesnot mentioned because they can be fairlyconfidentof each other'sloyaltyin theultimatecontingency. But when the agreement is ambiguous, they may find it necessary to stand by the ally in all situationsto prove their loyalty.Thus, France and Russia, bound by a quite specificagreementlimited to the contingencies of German or Austrian militaryattack,were each able to withhold support in several crises in the pre-I9I4 decade where only the partner's interestswere at stake, with little damage to the alliance. England, however,tied onlylooselyto France and Russia, feltcompelled 9 Austria also had a strategicinterestin Germany's not being absorbed by Russia, but thisinterestwas abstract-i.e., non-operational-sinceGermanywas quite capable ofholding her own against Russia, provided Russia had not previouslyconquered Austria. Thus, the situationwas analogous to the Franco-Britishrelationship.The general point is that the strongerally will be less directlydependentthan its partnerbut more indirectlydependent. Asymmetryof this kind is especiallypronounced in a bipolar world because of the wide disparityof power between the superpowersand theirallies. Thus the European members of NATO are highlydependenton the U.S. in the directsense,but the U.S. is not similarly dependenton them; on the otherhand, the U.S. is indirectlydependenton its allies because of its strategicinterestin containingSoviet power. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions WORLD POLITICS 474 lesttheydoubtherfidelity.io to supportthemin nearlyall confrontations factoris onlya modifierof the At bottom,however,theexplicitness effectsof the more basic dependenceand interestfactors.Vagueness tendsto inhibittheireffects. allows thesefactorsfullplay;explicitness Thus,asymmetrical dependencebyitselfwillcausethemoredependent butthisanxietywill be reducedbya formal, allyto fearabandonment, sucha contract willmakeit harderforthe explicitcontract. Conversely, at leaston issuesspecifiedin less dependentally to escapeentrapment, theagreement. A fourthdeterminant, affecting boththe riskof abandonmentand is the degreeto whichthe allies' interests that the riskof entrapment, are similar are in conflict withtheadversary are shared.If theseinterests and valuedwithaboutequal intensity, bothriskswillbe minimizedfor bothparties,sincepresumably (ceteris paribus)theywillbe aboutequally are quite readyto fightoverthem.On theotherhand,iftheirinterests each partnerwillworryaboutbeingtrappedinto"pullingthe different, out of thefire,"but each will also fearthattheother other'schestnuts For instance,in the are threatened. maystandaside ifhisown interests alliancebeforeWorldWar I, Francehad littleintrinsic Franco-Russian withAustriain the Balkans,while Russia interestin Russia'sconflicts had littleinterestin France's conflictswith Germany.When France hercommitment toRussiain I9I2, sheencouragedRussian strengthened thusincreasingherown dangerof beingentrapped.But aggressiveness, thiswasmorethanoffset bythereduceddangerofRussia'sabandonment of thealliancein a Franco-German war.The Frenchbythistimewere convincedthata war was virtuallyinevitable:it was desirablethatit fracasin the Balkans,therebyensuring beginwitha Russian-Austrian Russian participation. forcurrentstrategy and disincentives options Finally,the incentives will be affectedby one's own and others'behaviorin the recentpast. The determinants justdescribedare situationalratherthanbehavioral. of someitemsin thecalculus, Althoughtheyare fairlygood indicators or entrapment, suchas thecostsofabandonment theyyieldonlygeneral and uncertainjudgmentsabout theirlikelihood and about such other itemsas one's own or the ally'sloyaltyreputation. Expectationsabout --The best treatmentof this series of crises,beginningwith Morocco (I905) is still that of Luigi Albertini,The Originsofthe Warof 1914 (London: Oxford UniversityPress, I952), Vol. I. * The term"abandonment"is used here in the senseof renegingon one's specificalliance obligation,not as realignmentor de-alignment. of the French On Franco-Russianrelationsbetween I9I2 and I9I4 and the strengthening commitment,see G. P. Gooch, Beforethe War: Studiesin Diplomacy (London: Longmans, Green, i938), chap. 2. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 475 allies' future behavior and their probable expectationsof one's own behavior cannot be very preciselyarrived at from guesses about the others' "dependence," "interest,"and so on. Behavioral evidence supplements the situational elements to yield more specificand confident expectations.Thus, Britainand France were generallyconcernedabout Russian defection throughout the pre-I9I4 decade because of their knowledge of Russia's ratherlow dependence on the Triple Entente mostlybecause her option of realigningwith Germany was open until late in theperiod. They became more specificallyand intenselyconcerned when Russia negotiateda settlementof certaindisputes with Germany in i910. Of course, the ally's recentbehaviormay be in responseto one s own priorbehavior.The pointis thatthecontinuingsequence of strategic choicesbyall actorsyieldsa streamof behavioralevidencewhich interacts with estimatesof the general situationalfactorswhen the parties assess the probable consequences of currentstrategyoptions. These factors direct and indirectdependence, explicitnessof commitment,disparityof interestsin conflictwith the opponent, and the behavioral record are the principal determinantsof the values and likelihoods that the parties impute to the various possible consequences of strategyoptions as listed in Table i. These values and likelihoods, in turn,are the proximatedeterminantsof strategychoice itself. Thus, ifa statefeelshighlydependenton itsally,directlyor indirectly, if it perceives the ally as less dependent, if the alliance commitmentis vague, and if the ally's recent behavior suggests doubtful loyalty,the state will fear abandonment more than entrapment.It will therefore tend to reassure the ally of its commitment,support him in specific confrontationswith the opponent,and avoid conciliatingthe opponent. The reverseconditions will tend to induce opposite strategies. These propositionsmay be illustrated,though imperfectly, by certain differencesbetween Britishand French behaviortoward each otherand toward Germany from approximately I905 to 1909. Britain was not dependent on French aid in case of a direct German attack the navy could handle that. She was indirectlydependent on the Entente,however, because of her strategicinterestin a continentalbalance of power and her derivativeinterestin preventinga German conquest of France or a German-French alliance, eitherof which would make the British Isles vulnerable. France was perceived as less dependent because she already had an alliance with Russia in addition to an apparent option of realignmentor rapprochementwith Germany while England had no alliance alternatives.The vague language of the Entente Cordiale of I904 placed little constrainton French realignment.The British did This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 476 WORLD POLITICS in a Franco-German war overspeworrysomewhataboutentrapment cificFrenchinterests, but thisconcernwas less importantthan their anxietiesaboutFrenchdefection. The resultof theseconsiderations was a policyofreassurance toward Franceand firmness towardGermany.This reducedthe riskof abandonmentat thecostof someincreasedriskof entrapmentin case the of towardGermanyin theirconfidence Frenchbecametoo intransigent Britishsupport.However,the lattercost was small: Britainhad little leverageforrestraining Francein anycasebecauseofFrenchknowledge of Britishstrategicinterests. The firmstancetowardGermanywould deterGermanyifshewereaggressively inclined,butitriskedprovoking an insecurity spiral if she were not. Sir Edward Grey,the Foreign as a prudent Minister, entertained bothpossibilities, butchosefirmness with in the adversarygame; it was also consistent worst-casestrategy his alliancegame strategy of reassuring France. AlthoughFrance valued the Entente,she was less dependenton it thanEngland not becauseshe would not need help in a war against Germany,butbecauseshe did notbelieveEnglandcouldprovidemuch perceivedthestrongBritishstrategic helpin a land war.Francecorrectly a Franco-Germanreinterestin defendingFrance and in preventing alignment.She was also reassuredbyunqualifiedBritishsupportin the Moroccocrisisof I905. Therefore,France had littlereasonto doubt Britishloyaltyand feltlittleneed to reassurethe Britishof her own loyaltyin orderto avoid abandonment.Instead,she exploitedBritish anxietiesaboutFrenchloyaltyin orderto get a firmerBritishcommittalksand an implicit ment principally in theformofjointmilitary staff forceto theContinentin case Britishpledgeto send an expeditionary of war. France had some fearof entrapment in a war resultingfrom the Anglo-Germannaval race; partlyfor this reason,she adopted a forconof Germany.Otherincentives policyof moderateconciliation ciliation camefromtheFranco-German adversary game.Powerful groups in Francewanteda rapprochement withGermanyat thistime,bothto compensateforFrenchand Russianmilitaryweaknessand to secure commercialand colonialbenefitsby deals withGermanyin the Near withGermany East and Africa.These incentives producedan agreement over Moroccoin i909, which,of course,further increasedBritishconcernsabouta possibleFrenchrealignment.12 12On Anglo-French-Germanrelationsduring this period, see K. A. Hamilton, "Great and D. W. Sweet, "Great Britain and Germany, I905Britain and France, 1905-1911," I9II," in F. H. Hinsley,ed., BritishForeignPolicy UnderSir Edward Grey(Cambridge,:At the UniversityPress, 1977), chaps. 5 and ii. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 477 Thus, actual and perceived asymmetriesof direct and indirect dependlence,differencesin particularinterestsvis-at-visthe opponent, the vagueness and fragilityof the Entente,and the behavioral record combined to produce differentstrategiesby France and Britain in both the alliance and adversarygames. ON SPIRALS In the adversarysecuritydilemma, "D" strategiesof firmness,played between adversarieswho believe each other to be potentiallyaggressive but who really are not, produce an "insecurityspiral" i.e., a spiral of power/securitycompetition that feeds on each party's fears that the An analogous spiral other'sdefensivemoves are aggressivelymotivated.&3 in the alliance securitydilemma is an "integrativespiral,"in which allies move progressivelycloser out of theirmutual fearof abandonment.The integrativespiral interlockswith the insecurityspiral in the adversary game i.e., the two spirals are mutually reinforcing.Thus, allies play reciprocal"C" strategiesout of fear that the partnermay defectif they do not show support; theyfurtherattemptto reduce the partner'sanxieties by standing firm against the opponent; the opponent then feels threatenedand encircled, and his hostile response increases the allies' incentive to close ranks; when they do, the adversary becomes more fearfuland hostile,and, feelingmore dependenton his own allies,moves closer to them; in reaction,the firstalliance furthersolidifies,and so on. The Anglo-French Entente of I904 and the German reaction to it set in motion an alliance integrativespiraland an interlockingadversary insecurityspiral that continued until the outbreak of war in I9I4. The Entente had not initiallybeen intended as a quasi-alliance against Germany,but only as a colonial settlementand as a hedge against involvement in the impendingwar betweenthe parties'respectiveallies Japan and Russia. But Germany did see it as a threatand challenged it in the Morocco crisisof I905 in an attemptto break it up by exposing British infidelity.However, Britain stood firmlybehind France; the result of the Germans' coercion was a self-confirmation of theirown hypothesis: the Entente was transformedinto a quasi-alliance against the newly revealed German threat. The tighteningof the Entente set in motion an insecurityspiral in 3 What I call the insecurityspiral is sometimesreferredto as the securitydilemma. I believe this is a mislabeling,however,since the spiral is an outcomeof both adversaries' choosing one of the options in the securitydilemma, not theproblemof choice itself.The of choosingbetween two options,each of definingfeatureof any dilemma is the difficulty which will have more or less unsatisfactory consequences. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 478 WORLD POLITICS theadversary game,chiefly betweenGermanyand England.The latter, feelingmore dependenton France as evidenceof German hostility carefully mounted(especiallyvia theAnglo-German navalcompetition) movestowardGermanythat avoided,or limited,any accommodative mightraise doubts in French minds about Britishloyaltyand thus possiblytrigger a Frenchrealignment withGermany.'4 Shealsoincreased For hercommitment to Francebyinitiating military staffconversations. of Ententehostility now seemedto be even Germany,the hypothesis morestrongly confirmed by theBritishreserveand thespectacleof the partners movingclosertogether. Germanysteppedup hership-building and drewcloserto Austria.Thus,theincreasedsolidarity in one alliance, interacting withan insecurity spiralin the adversarygame,increased thecohesionof theotheralliance. These spiralscontinuedwiththeAnglo-Russian Ententeof I907 and the Bosnian crisisof i908-i909. The Anglo-Russian agreement,like the earlierAnglo-French ofvariouscolonial one,was on itsfacea settlement conflicts, but forBritainit was also (unlikethe FrenchEntente)conthebalanceof poweragainstGermany. sciouslyintendedto strengthen and felt Germanyperceivedit as anotherstep in her encirclement, increasingly dependenton Austria.During the Bosniancrisis,fearing and, by issuing Austriandefection, she supportedher ally completely an ultimatum, she forcedRussiato back down. She also expandedthe to Austria.Whereastheallianceforscopeof heralliancecommitment mallycalledformutualsupportagainstRussiaonlyin a defensivewar, war. Germanynow assuredAustriaof fullsupportevenin an offensive not to thepoint Britainalso supportedRussiaduringthecrisis,although of offering military assistance.The resultof thecrisiswas thusto conto extendthescopeof theGerman-Aussolidatebothalliancesystems, trianone, and to increasethelevelof tensionbetweenthetwo.'5 The integrative processcontinuedon the Ententeside withBritish supportof France duringthe second Morocco crisis(I9 II),i6 and a betweenFranceand England, firmingand extensionof commitments connection and betweenFranceand Russia,in I9I2. The French-British was tightenedby an agreementon a naval divisionof labor in which and the Britishfleet the Frenchfleetwas to guard the Mediterranean was to guard the Atlanticcoastsof bothcountries.In returnforthis '4George Monger, The End of Isolation(London: Nelson, I963), chap. I 2. BernadotteSchmitt,The Annexationof Bosnia (Cambridge: At the UniversityPress, I937). i6 Ima C. Barlow, The Agadir Crisis(Chapel Hill: Universityof North Carolina Press, 5 I 940). This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 479 arrangement,France successfullydemanded an exchange of notes that strengthenedthe Britishdiplomatic commitment.'7 The bolsteringof theFrench-Russianalliance occurredmainlybecause of France's increasinganxietyabout possible Russian defection.Russian dependence on France was declining because of Russia's steadily increasing militarystrength.Moreover, she had demonstratedsome independence by failingto supportFrance during the I9II Morocco crisis and by settlingsome minor conflictswith Germany in the Near East. France became worried that Russia mightbe induced to remain neutral in a Franco-German war. She dealt with the problem by extendingthe scope of her commitmentto Russia, implicitlypromisingaid not just in case of a German (or German-Austrian)attack on Russia (as per the termsof the treaty)but also in case Russia was forcedto attack Austria because of an Austrian militaryinitiative in the Balkans. This was analogous to the extension-ofthe German commitmentto Austria after the Bosnian crisis.I8 The integrative/insecurity spiral was partially-but only temporarwhen England ily interruptedduring the Balkan Wars (1912-I9I3), and Germany managed to fashion a detente based on collaborative restraintof theirallies. THE RESTRAINING THE BALKAN ALLIES WARS DILEMMA: INTERLUDE When members of opposite alliances become involved in a crisis confrontation,theirallies may find themselvesin a special formof the composite securitydilemma in which the alliance and adversarycomponents are closely linked. The dilemma is not just whetherto support or restrainthe ally, but whether to support the ally or to collaborate with the noninvolved state on the opposite side in restrainingboth protagonists.As in the classic prisoner'sdilemma, the opposite restraining stateshave a good deal to gain by cooperating-in keeping the peace and avoiding entrapment-but theyare also motivatedagainstcooperation by the desire to avoid alienating their allies. The best outcome '7Samuel R. Williamson,Jr.,The Politicsof Grand Strategy(Cambridge: Harvard UniversityPress, i969), providesan excellentaccount of these French-Britishnegotiations;see chaps. i i and I 2. x8 It is interesting that France tightenedher alliance with Russia by increasingher own commitment,but strengthenedher Britishconnectionby extractinga firmercommitment from England. The explanation for the differenceis that the "balance of dependence" betweenFrance and Russia favoredRussia,whereasbetweenFrance and England, it favored France. In other words, France enjoyed more bargainingpower over England than over Russia. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 480 WORLD POLITICS one's own ally while the admay be obtainedby secretlysupporting versaryrestrainshis; but if bothpartiespursuethisstrategy (perhaps theresultis thetypical out of suspicionthattheotheris doublecrossing) dilemma in thiscase,mutualentrap"DD" outcomeof theprisoner's ment. The BalkanWars of I9I2-I9I3 engaged Britainand Germany in this sortof dilemma. Their allies, Russia and Austria respectively, supported opposite sides among the Balkan states who firststripped Turkey of most of her European territoryand then foughtanother war among themselvesover thedivisionof the spoils.England and Germanyreached an informalagreement:England was to restrainRussia fromintervening, Germany to restrainAustria. The collaborationworked initially.Acting througha conferenceof all the great powers, the two peacemakers did restrain their allies and enforced compromise settlements.Formally, England and Germany both played "C" in the adversarygame and "D" in the alliance game, risking the loss of their allies in order to avoid entrapmentin a conflictover issues in which neitherhad much intrinsic interest.Apparently,the integrative/insecurity spiral of the preceding years had been stopped. This cooperative achievement,however, was due to a special combinationof factorsand, ironically,its success generatedforcesthatmade its repetitionunlikely.For Germany,the payofffor collaborationwith England was illusorilymagnifiedby the vain hope that it would lead to an Anglo-German neutralitypact, which Germany had been seeking for years. This hope outweighed the risk of alienating Austria, a risk thatwas low because the governmentin Vienna was itselfdivided about riskinga confrontationwith Russia. As forEngland, she was now more willing than before to take a chance on Russian defectionbecause her dependence on the Russian and French ententeshad declined. England's dependence had always been indirect,based on her strategicinterestin a continentalequilibrium.In I9I2-I9I3, such an equilibriumwas at least being approached, by virtueof a substantialincreasein Russian military strengthand the growing solidarityof the Russian-Frenchalliance. A British commitmentwas thereforeless necessary to deter the central powers, and Russia and France were less likely to realign if theybegan to doubt Britishloyalty.In the adversarygame, the Britishbalance of incentiveshad shiftedsomewhat fromdeterrenceto conciliation,and in the alliance game her balance of worries had shifted from fears of abandonmentto fearsof entrapment.The Britishpayoffin collaborating with Germany was furtherincreased by Sir Edward Grey's desire to dampen the insecurityspiral by easing German fears of encirclement, This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 481 and by the desireto gain more leverageover Russia in the persistent squabbleswith her over Persia. Finally,Britain'scost in restraining Russiawas minimizedby thefactthattheRussiangovernment was as dividedand vacillatingabout riskingwar as the Austriangovernment was.'9 THE SIR STRADDLE EDWARD GREY STRATEGY: IN JULY I9I4 The Anglo-German cooperation of the Balkan Wars did not carry over into the crisis of JulyI9I4, chieflybecause Germany's balance of incentiveshad changed sharplyby then.The growthof Russian military power, the initiation of Anglo-Russian naval conversations,and the increasingtensionbetween the continentalalliances had increased Germany's sense of dependence on Austria. This, combined with Austria's reproaches for her weak support during the Balkan Wars, increased German fears of Austrian defection: Austria must not be restrained again. Germany's feelingthatwar was inevitableled to the thoughtthat it had betterbe now than later, when Russia would be even stronger. Her incentiveto cooperate with England had declined with the evaporation of the dream of a neutralitypact, although German leaders continued to believe that England might well stand aside in a war in which Russia could be made to appear the aggressor.By Julyof I9I4, Germany was no longerin a security"dilemma," strictlyspeaking,since she had resolvedit on the side of definitesupportof her ally and firmness toward her opponents.The same was trueof France and Russia: Russia, like Austria, was determinednot to back down again, and France repeatedly avowed her unflinchingloyalty. In England, however, Sir Edward Grey's dilemma was as severe as ever: his incentivesfor eitheroption in both the alliance and adversary games were about evenlybalanced. In the alliance game, thiswas largely the resultof the apparent equilibriumof power on the continent,which lessened Britain's need to stand by her allies. If they could hold their own against the central powers, they were less likely to defect out of fear of British defection.In the adversarygame, Grey hoped to keep alive the detentewith Germanythathad been nourishedby theamicable settlementof certaincolonial disputesin the springand summerof I9I4. Thus Grey's worries about the intransigenceof Britain'sallies were at 19The classic studyof the Balkan Wars is E. C. Helmreich,The Diplomacyof theBalkan emWars (Cambridge: Harvard UniversityPress, I938). For a more recentinterpretation phasizingAnglo-Germanrelations,see R. J.Crampton,TheHollow Detente(London: George Prior Publishers,I979). This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 482 WORLD POLITICS least as strongas his fearsof theirdesertion,and he was as eager to avoidprovoking Germanyas todeterher.The twohornsofthedilemma appearedaboutequallyattractive (orunattractive). Greytherefore adopted a straddle a mixed "C-D" strategy in boththe allianceand the adversarygames. He gave vague reassurances to France and Russia,rejectingtheirpleas foran unambiguousdeclarationof armed support. He issueda fewmild warningsto Austriaand Germany,but concentratedon revivingthe joint Anglo-Germanmediationof the Balkan Wars.The lattereffort failedbecauseGreydid notappreciatetheextent towhichGermanpayoffs had changedsinceI9I2-I9I3. Germanyagreed to collaborate in joint restraintof Austria and Russia, but defected by goading Austria on. In the overall straddle, it was Grey's hope that Russia would be restrained without being alienated while Germany would be deterredwithoutbeing provoked. This strategyfailed because France-Russia and Austria-Germany,all thinkingwishfully,drew oppositeconclusionsfromit. France and Russia counted on Britishsupport while Germany and Austria expected Britishneutralityuntil the very last moment. Thus, in strivingfor the best of all worlds, Grey got the worst. If, early in the crisis,he had declared his firmsupportof Russia and France and warned Germany unequivocally,or if he had clearly declared to France and Russia that Britain would not fight,the war might have been averted.20This is not to argue that Grey's ambiguity was a centralcause of the outbreak of World War I. But England was the only major power that still had both polar options available; in failingto exerciseeitherone, she gave up a chance to preventthe war.2' We should not conclude fromthissinglecase, however,thata straddle strategyin the composite securitydilemma cannot work, thatone must firmlygrasp one horn or the other.Special circumstancesin I9I4 made it virtuallyinevitablethatthe continentalpowers would interpretBritish intentionswishfully.These circumstanceswere,first,thatthecontinental powers were firmlylocked into a collision course: Austria and Russia via theirdeep conflictof interestin the Balkans, Germany and France because of theirhigh dependence upon and firmcommitmentsto their Historiansare divided as to whetherGreycould have avertedthe war by takinga clear stance one way or the other.Albertini'sopinion (fn. 10, Vol. II, 514), is that he could have. Masteryin Europe (London: Oxford For a contraryview, see A.J.P. Taylor, The Strugglefor UniversityPress, I954), 525. For a discussionof Grey's dilemma, see Michael J. Eckstein, "Great Britain and the Triple Entente on the Eve of the Sarajevo Crisis," in Hinsley (fn. I 2), chap. i 8. considerationsfrom 21It is true thatGrey feltconstrainedby domesticand constitutional issuing an unequivocal commitment.The factthateventuallyhe did issue a clear warning to Germany that England could not remain neutral-although it came too late to affect German decision making-indicates that these constraintswere not absolute. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 483 ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA spiral within and between the contiallies. The integrative/insecurity so tightly wound by the summer of I9I4 nental alliances had become that,in order to have any chance of reversingit, Grey would have had to choose one of his extreme options. Second, British power was not considered so decisive for the outcome of a war that the other states were unwilling to gamble with the uncertaintyof its being used. Third, both sides on the Continent had grounds for optimisticexpectations about England, generated by recentinteractionswith her. With differentbackgroundconditions,a straddlemightbe successful. Success means instillingcautious (and, hence, opposite) expectationsin the ally and the adversary,ratherthan wishful(and opposite) ones, and doing so without unduly antagonizing eitherparty.One wants the ally to think one probably will not fight,and the opponent to think one probablywill. The ambiguityof a straddleis mostlikelyto be interpreted cautiously in circumstancesmore or less opposite to those of 1914: the conflictof interestbetween ally and adversaryis relativelymild, they are not firmlycommitted against each other, and one's own military power is expected to determinethe outcome of a war. Then the other parties' costs of being restrainedor deterred,or of acceptinga compromise settlement,would be low compared to the expected cost of a war (and defeat)resultingfroma mistakenpredictionofone's own intentions. A mixed past record containing instances of both non-supportof the ally and strongresistanceto the opponent would also be helpful. Such conditionswere approximatedin relationsbetween Russia, Austria,and Germany in the i870s and i88os, when Bismarck played the straddle option successfullyon several occasions.22 THE ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA IN A BIPOLAR SYSTEM The alliance securitydilemma is sharplytruncatedin today's bipolar system because one of the central "bads" that of abandonment is 22These remarkscan no more than suggestthe complexityof the straddleproblem.One aspect of this complexityis that one is tryingto optimize among four objectives: restrain the ally,but avoid alienatinghim; deterthe opponentbut avoid provokinghim. Justwhat mixtureof communicationsis likely to optimize will be difficultto estimate,even if one could assume thattheywill be interpretedas desired by both other parties.Anotheraspect is the necessaryambiguityof one's messages, which makes it unlikelythat they will be interpretedexactlyas desired.The possibleporosityof diplomaticcommunicationchannels limitsthe extentto which signals sent to the ally and adversarycan be inconsistentwith each other-e.g., signalsto the ally thatlean toward restraintand messagesto the opponent thatemphasize firmness.The "pure" and consistentstrategiesof restrainingthe ally while conciliatingthe adversary,or supportingthe ally while warningthe opponent,are less likely to be misread,and eitherone may well keep the peace, but theyrisk alienatingthe ally or theselatterrisks,a mixedstrategy theopponent's promByminimizing hostility. increasing outcomethaneitherofthepureones,butalso risksa worseoutcome, especially isesa better conditions whenthebackground approachthosein I9I4. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 484 WORLD POLITICS highlyunlikely.At leastthatis so fortheEuropeancentralarenaof the The superto whichthefollowingdiscussionwill be limited.23 system, powersare solidlycommittedby theirown intereststo defendtheir allies, hence theirde-alignmentis irrational.Realignmentwith each otheris logicallyimpossible, simplybecausethereis no otherstatepowerfulenough to providea motive.The European allies theoretically could shiftsidesifleftto theirown devices.However,thesuperpowers havepowerfulincentives to preventtheirrealignment byforceifnecessary as the Sovietshave demonstrated. The West Europeanstates have no motiveto realign,sincetheSovietUnionis theprincipalthreat Finally, totheirsecurity and theUnitedStatesis theirnaturalprotector.24 simplede-alignment by the smallerstatesis ultimately illusory,since theirprotector will defendthemno matterwhatpoliticalposturethey assume. is possible,however.Conceivably, boththesuperpowers Entrapment and theiralliescould be pulledunwillingly in Europe by intoa conflict one partner'sinitiative forinstance,involvement of theWestGerman The smalleralliesmustworryin armyin an East Germanrevolution. additionabout extraregional entrapment (the spilloverintoEurope of a superpowerconflictoriginatingin otherareas),and about nuclear nuclearwarfarein Europe in the entrapment (a superpowerinitiating is a more hope thatit mightbe confinedthere).In general,entrapment seriousconcernforthe lesserallies thanforthe superpowersbecause because the theyshare only a portionof the latter'sglobal interests, havea muchgreatercapacityfortakinginitiatives superpowers (notably nuclearinitiatives), and becausethe allies' capacityto restrainthe superpowersis muchsmallerthanvice versa. Since the alliance dilemma is mostlya functionof tensionbetween the risk of abandonmentand the risk of entrapment-reducing one tendsto increasetheother-the dilemmais weak in a bipolaralliance, becauseonlyone of theserisksis significantly present.That risk,enfromtheally'spolicy, can be dealtwithsimplybydissociation trapment, or by variousmeans of restraining the ally,withoutconcernthatthe ally may defectin consequence.The superpowermay exerteconomic pressureor simplywithholdsupportfromtheally'sadventures(as the 23 Jbelieve the presentsystemshould still be classifiedas bipolar,even though there has been some movementtoward multipolarity.Although some of my theoreticalstatements in this section apply to bipolarityin Europe in general, they are much more relevantto NATO than to the Warsaw Pact, as my examplesclearlyindicate.Bipolar alliances outside Europe have somewhatdifferentdynamics,which cannot be explored here. 24 Some mightargue that the West European countriesare allied with the United States withthe Soviet Union), not beqause out of culturaland ideologicalaffinities (and disaffinities did not exist,alignmentwith the of structuralcompulsion.However, even if theseaffinities U.S. would be dictatedby theirsecurityinterests. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 485 United States did during the Suez crisisof I956). The weaker allies may also fail to support, or even hinder, the superpower's actions (as the Europeans did during the Yom Kippur War and on the recent gas pipeline issue); theymay also be able to exercisesome restrainingleverage by appealing to consensusnormsor by exploitingthe superpower'sneed for collective legitimization.In so doing, they do not risk losing the superpower's protection.Neither the superpower nor its protegesneed feel any compulsion to supporteach other (and therebyaccept increased risksof entrapment)solelyto insureagainst the alliance's collapse. When support is provided against the adversary,it is chieflybecause the allies share each other's interestsand perceptionsin the adversarygame, not because they fear the partnermight otherwise leave the fold. Finally, neitherthe greaternor the smaller allies are inhibitedfromconciliating the adversaryby the worry-typical of multipolaralliances-that such conciliationmight precipitatethe ally's realignment. Because of the weakness of the alliance securitydilemma, the adversary dilemma dominates. That dilemma can be dealt with by each partneraccording to its own preferences,with littleconcernforalliance "side effects."The superpowersand theirallies may disagreeabout policy toward the adversary, and, as in NATO at present, they may even pursue contradictorypolicies. But they need have little fear that their own association is therebyendangered. Indeed, it is largelybecause the alliance itselfis fundamentallystable that such policy divergencesmay develop and persist. The alliance is stable because it is essentiallya product of the structureof the system and of the common security interestsgenerated thereby.So long as thatstructureand those interests persist,the allies are free to disagree. By contrast,in a multipolarsystemwhere the alliance and adversary dilemmas are roughly co-equal, allies are much more constrained in their play of the adversary game by the possible consequences to the alliance. In particular,theyare inhibitedfromconciliatingthe adversary forfear the ally will take it as a prelude to realignment,and will realign preemptively.Since multipolar alignmentsare not determinedby the structureof the system,but are formedby choice among severaloptions, theyare unstable and vulnerable to policy disagreement.Worries about alliance disintegrationthus tend to induce similarityof policy toward the opponent. In a mulitpolaralliance there is a close link between the degree of policy solidarityand the stabilityof the alliance; in a bipolar alliance that link is tenuous at best.25 25 For a similarargument, Politics(Reading, see KennethN. Waltz, TheoryofInternational Mass.: Addison Wesley, I979), esp. i69-70. This essay has been considerablyinfluencedby Waltz's impressivework. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 486 WORLD POLITICS Although the alliance securitydilemma is weak in a bipolar system, it is not entirelyabsent. There are partialsurrogatesforabandonment various degrees of movementaway fromtheally or toward the opponent that give rise to truncatedformsof the dilemma. Differenttypes can be discerned at the political and militarylevels. At the political level, the most extreme conceivable approaches to abandonment are "condominium" for the superpowers and "finlandization" or "neutralization"forthe lesser states.Condominium means a high degree of collaboration by the superpowers to maintain order in the system,and subordination of their competitiveinterestsand the interestsof theirallies to thisgoal. Logically,condominiumis more akin to multipolar"concert"than to realignment,and is not inconsistentwith a continued intentionto defend allies against actual attack. However, the allies might still have reason to worry about not being supported over less-than-ultimateissues,and about losing whateverpoliticalinfluence theycurrentlyenjoy as a consequence of superpower rivalry. Finlandization or neutralizationare also just barely conceivable. In an ultimate sense, both are illusions. Although it is possible that some European NATO members might driftin these directionsout of fear of being abandoned by the United States or, conversely,of being entrappedin a conflictbetweenthe superpowers,such stanceswould amount only to "pseudo-abandonment" so long as the U.S. retainedits intention to defend them. NATO, like any bipolar alliance, is essentiallya guarantee of the lesser states by the superpower; as long as the guarantee holds, the alliance holds-whatever postures the smaller states may strike.This does not mean, however,thatthe degree of West European accommodation with the Soviets is unimportant.If West Germany,say, were to come under significantSoviet influence,importantcosts forthe U.S. and the Western alliance would be entailed, even if the alliance per se remained intact. Within these extremes-that is, within the realm of the possibleare various degrees of "detente"with the adversary,each involvingsome degree of cooperative benefitsand some dependence on the adversary for continuance of the benefits,and hence, some influenceby the adversary.Specific moves toward detente, by either the superpowers or theirproteges,may generatefearsthatfurthermoves thatwould weaken alliance obligations are impending. Typically, the fears exceed what is likely to happen, much as fearsof realignmentin the multipolarworld are quite disproportionateto the real possibilities-states are notoriously paranoid -but, of course, it is the subjective fears ratherthan the objective possibilitiesthat influencetheirbehavior. Thus, in the truncated This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 487 alliance game of bipolarity,simply the reduction of tension between adversaries,or its possibility,is functionallyequivalent to potentialdefectionor realignmentas a source of abandonment anxiety. An obvious militarysurrogatefor abandonment would be a partial U.S. troop withdrawal fromEurope. (A completewithdrawal is hardly conceivable.) Although this would not seriouslyimpair the U.S. commitmentto Europe, it would certainlystimulateever-lurkingEuropean worries about a U.S. retreatto the American "fortress." The alliance dilemma forthe U.S. at the politicallevel is a by-product of the adversarydilemma-of the choice between conciliatingor confrontingthe adversary.Unlike themultipolarversion,it does not involve a trade-offbetween risksof abandonmentand risksof entrapment,but rathera balancing between two kinds of incentivesfor partial "abandonment" by the smaller states.As Henry Kissingerhas noted,the West Europeans tend to oscillate between fearsof collusion and fearsof collision betweentheUnited Statesand theSoviet Union, and theirresponse to bothfearsis to conciliatethe Soviets.26Their motivesforthisresponse to superpower collusion presumablyare (i) to hedge against a possible weakening of the American will to protecttheirinterests;(2) to preserve some bargainingpower vis-a-visthe United States;or (3) simplyto share in the benefitsof betterrelationswith the Soviet Union. When theyfear collision (entrapment),their incentivesto conciliate the Soviet Union may be (i) to restrainU.S. intransigence;(2) to insulate theirown good relationswith the Soviets fromthe superpowerconfrontation;and perhaps (3) to offsetU.S. belligerence,thus moderatingthe overall alliance stance and reducing the risk of provoking the Soviets. Thus, forthe United States,thealliance dilemma presentsthe problem of findingthe optimum blend of firmnessand accommodation toward the Soviets-that which generates the least incentivefor the allies to "neutralize" or "finlandize." Since the U.S. will have its independent preferencesin the adversary game, which might point to a different optimum stance in that game, the overall problem is one of optimizing between two optimums. Henry Kissingerstatedtheproblemclearlywhen he warned President Nixon in I973: We had to remainsoberin our dealingswiththe SovietUnion. If we ofa U.S. becametooimpetuoustheEuropeannationswouldgrowfearful ... Sovietdeal. This would cause themto multiplytheirown initiatives withtheU.S.S.R. to protect themselves, bymakingtheirown arrangements the same would happenif the U.S. remainedin the But paradoxically, 26 Kissinger,The WhiteHouse Years(Boston: Little,Brown, 1979), 382. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 488 WORLD POLITICS trenches oftheCold War. In thatcaseEuropeanleaderswouldbe tempted to appearbeforetheirpublicsas "mediators"betweenbellicosesuperpowers. The U.S. had to conducta carefulpolicytowardstheSovietUnion: sufficiently strongto maintainthe interestin the commondefense;sufflexibleto preventour alliesfromracingto Moscow.27 ficiently This strategyis appropriate when a superpower is most concerned about the effectsof its own strategyupon that of the allies. When the concern is that the ally is "defecting"on its own initiative,however, a betterstrategymightbe to preempt.For example, Nixon and Kissinger worried in the early seventiesthat the West German Ostpolitik might go too far; this stimulated them to move ahead with theirown negotiations lest Germany be left alone in the Soviet embrace. Kissinger reportsthat he dreaded the moment "when no German chancellorcan affordthe hostilityof the Soviet Union . . .": This uneasinessabout the driftof Brandt'spolicieswas sharedby his principalpartnersin the Westernalliance.... To forestall[independent GermanmaneuveringbetweenEast and West],or perhapsoutflankit, each of Brandt'scolleagues-includingNixon-sought to pre-emptGermanyby conductingan activedetentepolicyof its own. In thissense, to a race farbeyondthoseintended.It contributed Ostpolitikhad effects to Moscowand overtimeheightened mutualsuspicionamongtheallies.28 When the U.S.-Soviet detente negotiationswere well underway,the bogeyof "condominium" was raised in Europe- notablyaftertheagreement on Prevention of Nuclear War in I973, which seemed to imply jointSoviet-U.S. managementof crisesand disputesbetweenotherstates. At that point, the European states felt impelled to deepen their own detentein order to hedge against the possibilitythatWashington's commitment to its allies was weakening. Willy Brandt noted that one of his motives for Ostpolitik was his belief that only a part of U.S. forces would still be in Europe at the end of the seventies.29 However, the most importantmotives for detente on both sides of the Atlanticwere autonomous ones stemmingfromthe adversarygame, and the reduced cohesion of NATO was more the resultof the reduced Soviet threat than of mutual fears of defectionamong the allies. Nor did fearsof the partners'defectionseriouslyinhibitthe detente policies of either the U.S. or Europe-despite Kissinger's warning. There is no bipolar parallel to the integrativespiral that occurred in Ibid., 382. Kissinger,Yearsof Upheaval(Boston: Little,Brown, I980), I45-46. 29 Willy Brandt,Begegnungen und Einsichten.Die Jahreig60-i975 (Hamburg: Hoffmann & Campe, I976), 348, cited in Karl Kaiser and Hans-Peter Schwarz, Americaand Western Europe: Problemsand Prospects(Lexington,Mass.: Lexington Books, I977), 229. 27 28 This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 489 the pre-I9I4 alliances. Such a spiral may occur in a multipolar system because alliance commitmentsare always somewhat in doubt; henceespecially during periods of rising tension-there are tendencies to strengthenand expand commitmentsin order to guard against abandonment,tendenciesthat at the same time generate and are reinforced by an insecurityspiral between adversaries. In a bipolar alliance such as NATO, the basic alliance commitmentis not in doubt since it is structurallyordained; there is little scope or incentiveto strengthenit by acts of policy,and thereis hence no integrativespiral. An insecurity spiral may develop independentlyin the adversarygame, and NATO's policy cohesion may increase in response to common perceptionsof a risingexternalthreat,but these processesare not additionallydriven by fearsof desertionby allies.30 THE CURRENT NATO CRISIS AND THE SECURITY DILEMMA The presentconflictbetween the United Statesand itsEuropean allies is chieflya disagreementabout how to deal with the adversarysecurity dilemma. Each side of the alliance prefersa differentstrategytoward the Soviet Union, and each either advocates or independentlypursues its own preferredstrategy.The United States prefersa "D" strategyof toughnessand confrontation;the Europeans generallya moderate "C" strategyof conciliation. Their strategiesin the alliance game are consistentwith, though more or less incidental to, theirfavored strategies in the adversarygame. The United States perceivesitselfas increasing its support for its allies by building up its capabilityfordeterrenceand defense, in Europe as well as in peripheral areas where it perceives European intereststo be at least as great as its own. The Europeans are divided, but mostly skeptical about U.S. nuclear policies. They resist U.S. pressuresto increase theirown conventionalforces;theyalso resist U.S. tendenciesto make detentea hostageto Soviet behaviorin the third world,and theyobstructWashington'sattemptsto apply economic sanctions against the Soviets. Some of the reasons forthis divergenceare extraneousto the present 3 Conversely,it ought to be easier for the bipolar superpowers than for multipolar adversariesto dampen or avoid insecurityspirals by conciliatingeach other, since their conciliationis so much less constrainedby alliance concerns.In the pre-I9I4 decade, Sir Edward GreyempathizedwithGermany'sinsecuritiesand fearsof encirclement;he realized that the steadytighteningof the Entente was provokingher, but he could do littleabout it because he fearedabandonmentby Russia and France if he tried.The U.S. and the Soviet Union do not have a similar problem.This is not to say that it is easy to escape fromor weaken insecurityspiralsin a bipolarsystem-it is merelyeasierbecause theattemptinvolves significantrisks in the adversarygame only. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 490 WORLD POLITICS theme-notably,the rise in Europe's economicstrength(which has generateda new spiritof assertiveness againsttheU.S. in the security as well as theeconomicfields),and a decliningfaithin America'sleadershipcapacities.A roughassessmentof the weightsthatthe parties attachto the"goods"and "bads" ofthecompositesecurity dilemmaand of whytheseweightshave changed,mayprovidea further explanation. The reasonsfallintofoursomewhatoverlapping categories: (i) divergent images of the motivesand intentionsof the adversary;(2) different valuationsofdetente;(3) Europeanperceptions ofa decliningcredibility oftheU.S. deterrent inlightoftheSovietUnion'sachievement ofnuclear adventures to thethirdworld, parity;and (4) a shiftofSovietaggressive which has precipitateda conflictbetweenthe global interestsof the of theEuropeanallies. UnitedStatesand themorelimitedperspectives boththealliancedilemmaand theadversary These changeshaveaffected dilemma,butmostlythelatter. and value loadingson theadversarydilemmahave The perceptions Mostimportantly, changedsharplyforEuropesincetheearlyseventies.31 of course,thepoliticaland economicgainsfromdetentehave substantiallyincreasedthe incentiveto conciliatethe Soviets.The European becausetheyperstatessee no "resolvereputation" costsin conciliation ceiveSovietintentions as essentially defensive, possiblybecausetheSovietshave not been aggressivein Europe formorethan two decades. from This imagemaybe partlya wishfulone,supportedbythebenefits detente. towardtheSovietUnion The "goods"and "bads" ofa toughstrategy havealso changedwitha netincreaseforthe"bads."For theEuropeans, the deterrentvalue of firmnesshas declinedbecause of theirpacific imageof theSoviets,whilethedangerofprovokingan insecurity spiral has increased.Europe is disposedto invoke throughexcessivefirmness the "I9I4 analogy":the greatestdangerarisesnot fromthe powerful whichmightproduce butfromthedynamicsofconflict adversary, itself, a "war that nobody wanted."32Finally, too tough a stance might un- of detente. dermineprospectsforarmscontrol,thecenterpiece Americanperceptionsand values in the adversarydilemma have changedin theoppositedirection. ViewingSovietbehaviorand detente 3 The terms"European" and "American"are intendedto referto theapparentlydominant views among European and Americanelites.Obviously,thereis a wide spectrumof opinion on both sides of the Atlantic. 32 The I9I4 analogyis poorlytaken,sincethatspiralfedon factorspeculiarto a multipolar system-notably high and equal interdependenceamong allies. Also, recenthistoriography has suggestedthat World War I was a war that"somebody" (Germany) did want. See, for example, Fritz Fischer,Germany's Aimsin theFirstWorldWar (New York: W. W. Ndrton, i967). This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 491 froma global perspective, the UnitedStatesbegan to devaluedetente in'thelateseventies afterSovietadvancesin thethirdworld,and virtually wroteit offafterthe invasionof Afghanistan. The Reagan AdministrationperceivestheSovietUnionas an inherently aggressivestatethat will seize everyopportunity to expandby force,and will interpret any as weakness.Accordingly, conciliation and firmness deterrence are valued morehighly,while the riskof stimulating Sovietinsecurity and a spiralof risingtensionhas been downgraded,if not ignored.On the economicside,a strategy of economicdeprivation, designedto weaken theSovietUnion'smilitary potentialand economy,has beensubstituted forthe formerstrategy of inducingSovietaccommodation by weaving theU.S.S.R. intoa web of economicinterdependence. In thealliancegame,theEuropeansworryprincipally aboutentrapment.They fearthatexcessiveU.S. bellicosity mightset offa severe insecurity spiralwiththeSovietUnion,whichcould explodeintocrisis or violence.A more specificconcernis thatof extraregional entrapconflict causedbyan American ment-being caughtup in a superpower over-reaction toSovietadvancesin thethirdworld.Talk byU.S. military plannersof "horizontalescalation"has no doubt fueledthis anxiety. However,thefearprobablyis notso muchone of beingpulledintoan area as it is thattensionsgenerated actualwar begunin someperipheral in such areas mightbecomegeneraland destroydetentein Europe. of the Soviet hold on the East Anothercost would be a tightening Europeancountries, endingthe dreamof at leasta partialintegration is a of all of Europe. (Europeanconcernabout "nuclearentrapment" specialcase whichwill be discussedbelow.) The alliance dilemmaforthe European allies is how to escape or minimizetheserisksofentrapment withoutseriously riskingsomeform of partialU.S. abandonment.The lattermightconsistof troopwithofEuropeandefensein of thepriority drawals,Americandowngrading favorof otherareas such as the PersianGulf,or a furtherdriftto unilateralism. Althoughthe European alliancedilemmais somewhat sharperthan the U.S. dilemmadiscussedearlier,it is stillnot severe becauseany such partialabandonmentby theUnitedStateswould fall or itsnuclear well shortof totalwithdrawalof thelatter'scommitment deterrent. THE NUCLEAR DIMENSION I have chosento treattheissueof nuclearstrategy separately because it poses the risksof abandonmentand entrapment (and consequently thealliancedilemmaitself)in different forms.Simplyput,nuclearaban- This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 492 WORLD POLITICS donment means the loss of U.S. will to use its strategicweapons in defense of Western Europe; more precisely,that the credibilityof U.S. deterrencedrops below the level required to deter the Soviets. Europe has had reason to worry about this since the Soviet Union achieved a second-strikecapabilityin thelate fiftiesor earlysixties:therecentadvent of full parityapparentlyoperates as a kind of perceptualthresholdthat has greatlyheightenedEuropean anxiety.Of course,European concerns about such "decoupling" are not so much fears of actual U.S. nuclear abandonment as theyare worries that U.S. strategicnuclear forcesare no longer effectivein deterringthe Soviets. American proposals for a policy of no firstuse do raise fearsof deliberatenuclear abandonment. Thus, to Europe nuclear abandonmentmeans eithera withdrawalof the U.S. nuclear deterrentor an evaporation of its credibility.Nuclear entrapmentmeans the actual use of nuclear weapons in case deterrence fails,especiallyin a way thatmakes Europe the principalbattleground. Thus, the tension between nuclear abandonment and entrapmentis virtuallyequivalent to the familiartension between deterrenceand deor a capabilityand doctrinefor fense,the latterdefinedas war-fighting, fightinga nuclear war "rationally."Europeans have always favoredpure deterrenceover war-fightingpostures. Some, if not most, probably (if secretly)would prefera strategyof pure nuclear bluff:deterrenceby a threat of massive retaliation,but no retaliationat all if the threat is ineffective.Nuclear war-fightingand limited nuclear war strategiesfavored by the United States are resisted for at least three reasons: (i) they imply a greater likelihood, and greater degree, of devastation in Europe than a strategyof assured destruction,which seems to hold out at least some possibilityof a nuclear war being conducted intercontinentally,"over Europe's head"; (2) they might encourage the U.S. to initiatenuclear war too casually in the event of conventionalattack or to take excessive risks in a crisis; and (3) they are provocative to the Soviet Union, both politicallyand militarily. The nuclear issue presentsthe alliance dilemma to the Europeans in its severestform,and it is the issue about which Europe is most ambivalentor divided. By itself,the dilemma is whetherto supportAmerican effortsto strengthenextended deterrence,including intermediate nuclear forces (INF), at the risk of greater destructionin Europe if deterrencefails, or to resistthese efforts,therebysacrificingsome deterrencein the hope of limitingdamage to Europe. As on the political side of the dilemma, thereis a trade-offbetween the risks of abandonment and entrapment.The nuclear dilemma links up to the broader securitydilemma throughthe risk of alienating the United States if its This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 493 preferencesare opposed, and of damaging the Europe-Soviet detenteif theyare accepted. A furtherlink is providedby theoptionof conciliating the Soviets: if deterrenceis weakened by parity,perhaps the U.S.S.R.'s incentivesto attack can be weakened by increasingits stake in economic intercoursewith Western Europe-even if this means increasing Europe's vulnerabilityto Soviet influence. European governmentshave tentativelyresolvedthe nuclear dilemma by a contingentacceptance of INF, intended both to recouple the U.S. strategicdeterrentto Europe and to balance offtheSoviet SS-20. Damage to the European detentewill be minimized,theyhope, with only American fingerson the triggers.They tacitly,if reluctantly,accept the U.S. war-fighting doctrine.The package is roundedout bypoliticalassurances to the Soviets-or "reinsurance,"as formerchancellor Schmidt called it-presumably against eitherlower deterrencecredibilityif INF is not deployed or against Soviet ire if it is. Deployment was made contingent on a prioreffortat arms control;thesetalks,at thiswriting,have broken down and deploymentis underway, but whetherit will be completed as planned is uncertain. This is not the place to rehearse all the arguments,paradoxes, and political currentsgenerated by the INF issue. It is of interestfor our presenttheme in that it presentsEurope's nuclear alliance dilemma in quintessentialform:it is seen simultaneously(or by differentgroups) as insurance against American nuclear abandonment and as a source of European nuclear entrapment.33 Probably INF would shore up deterrence marginally. In contemplatinga conventionalattack, the Soviets probablywould perceive a greaterlikelihood of U.S. retaliationagainst their homeland with nuclear weapons based in Europe than with intercontinentalones, since the U.S. could at least hope the Soviets would limit theircounter-retaliationto Europe. (Indeed, Moscow would have a strongincentiveto so limit it to act as if the physicallocation of the weapons rather than the nationalityof the triggerfingerdictated the directionof theirresponse in the hope of avoiding settingoffthe whole U.S. strategicarsenal.) Alternatively,the Soviet Union might feel that an attack on Europe would have to startwith a preemptiveassault on INF, and would shrink from that for fear that so provocativean act would triggerfull-scale U.S. retaliation.But both of these deterrent arguments lead straightto the point made by the European Left that INF means greaterdamage to Europe in case deterrencefails,and the firstargument supports the view that it makes the United States more 33 A similarpoint is made by RobertJ. Art in "Fixing AtlanticBridges,"ForeignPolicy, No. 46 (Spring 1982), 77. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 494 WORLD POLITICS willing to initiate nuclear war. The Left in the European political spectrumtendsto focuson the danger of nuclear entrapmentthatINF poses, whereas the Right emphasizes its reductionof the risk of nuclear abandonment. No doubt the moderates feel the dilemma most intensely. CONCLUSION The securitydilemma occurs in relations between allies as well as between adversaries.In a multipolarsystem,the alliance and adversary dilemmas are of roughlyequal importanceand are closelyintertwined. Choices in each dilemma are constrainednot onlyby predictedor feared effectsinternal to itself,but also by side effectsin the other dilemma. In particular,strategychoices in the adversarygame-conciliation or firmness-are constrainedby fears of abandonment or entrapmentby allies. The alliance dilemma is more severe in a multipolarthan in a bipolar systembecause high mutual dependence coexistswith plausible realignment options. An ally's defectionis a calamity,yet distinctlypossible. Conciliating the adversary,or weakening one's support of the ally to guard againstentrapment,are bothconstrainedby fearsof abandonment. But attemptsto insure against abandonment by supportingthe ally and avoiding accommodation with the opponent increase the risk of entrapment;hence the dilemma. On the whole, however, abandonment worries outweigh entrapmentfears. The mutual fear of abandonment tends to promote convergenceof policy-typically convergenceon mutual support and firmnesstoward the adversary. The alliance securitydilemma is less severe in a bipolar systembecause-although fears of entrapmentexist-the risks of abandonment are low. The adversary dilemma dominates; strategychoices in that dilemma are not much constrainedby side effectsin the alliance game. The allies may adopt independent,indeed contradictory, policies toward the opponent with littlefearthatthe partnerwill defectin consequence. Thus, the tendency is toward divergence rather than convergence of policy.Although minor policydifferencesmay be resolvedby consensus norms,major differencestend to persistbecause thereis littlestructural pressuretoward theirresolution.And theirpersistencedoes not seriously threatenthe existenceof the alliance.34 It follows that those who see NATO's currentcrisisas heralding its collapse tend to confuse cause and effect.Although the disagreements 34 These remarksare, in effect, an elaborationof Kenneth Waltz's axiom that flexibility of alignmentin multipolarityproduces rigidityof strategy,while rigidityof alignmentin of strategy.Waltz (fn. 25). bipolaritypromotesflexibility This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALLIANCE SECURITY DILEMMA 495 have arisen froma varietyof proximatecauses,theypersistlargely because the alliance cannot break up. Since NATO is a product of the of the system,it cannotcollapseor changebasically bipolarstructure untilthatstructure guaranteeagainstdisintechanges.This structural and inhibitscompromise. grationencouragesunilateralism Policyconflictsmay not be resolvedbecausethe costof not resolvingthemdoes notincludea riskto theallianceitself.In contrast, thestructural instabilityof multipolaralliances-the factthattheycouldcollapse- tended to promoteconflict resolution and policyconsistency amongtheirmembers. The onlywayin whichintra-NATOconflict mightconceivably bring about the alliance'sdemise is througha radical revisionof the U.S. conceptionof its interests such thatit is no longersubjectto structural compulsion.It is conceivablethattheU.S., disillusioned withEuropean obstinacy, mightrelapseinto hemispheric isolation.This would mean as RobertTuckerand othershaveargued,35 recognizing, thatAmerica's in thenuclearage is notdependent physicalsecurity on keepingWestern Europe out of Soviethands;it would also indicatea substantial devaluationofthecultural,economic,and othernonsecurity valuesthathave It is also conceivablethatWestern motivatedthe U.S. commitment. foritsown defenseand Europemightuniteand takefullresponsibility of nucleardeterrence. This would amountto a changein thestructure orunnecessary. theinternational theallianceirrelevant system, rendering The likelihoodof eitherof theseeventsin the foreseeablefutureis will low. The alliancewill survive,whileitsinternalconflicts extremely continueto producemuchargumentbutlittleresolution untiltheSoviet Union once again appearsthreatening to to Europe or nonthreatening U.S. interests elsewhere,or untilpoliticalchangesin eithertheUnited Statesor Europe (or in both)generatemore harmoniouspolicypreferencestowardtheadversary. 35RobertW. Tucker and Linda Wrigley,eds., The AtlanticAllianceand Its Critics(New York: Praeger, I983), chap. 6. This content downloaded from 163.239.216.77 on Wed, 5 Nov 2014 22:57:51 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions