india i
Transcription
india i
INDIA INFRASTRUCTURE REPORT 2002 Editor: SEBASTIAN MORRIS Associate Editor: RAJIV SHEKHAR Project Co-ordinator: ANUPAM B. RASTOGI T.C.A. Anant R.V. Anuradha Samir K. Barua Atanu Chakraborty Puneet Chitkara Amita Chudgar Atiyah Curmally Bernard D’Mello Keshab Das Bithin Datta Lokesh Garg Subir Gokarn Mahendra Gujarathi Shreekant Gupta Rekha Jain Abha Singhal Joshi Piush Joshi Gopakumar K. Prem K. Kalra Bhavin Kothari Brij Kothari Praveen Kulshreshtha P. Nandini Kumar Venu Madhav S. Manikutty Mukesh P. Mathur Sebastian Morris Nirmal Mohanty Ajay Pandey Avinash Pandey Samuel Paul B.P. Pundir G. Raghuram K. Ramakrishnan T.V.S. Ramamohan Rao Anupam B. Rastogi Binayak Rath Dheeraj Sanghi Kaushal K. Saxena Mukesh Sharma Rajiv Shekhar Jaivir Singh Sidharth Sinha S. Sriraman Biju Varkkey Jayanth Varma Delhi School of Economics Independent Consultant, Mumbai Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Gujarat Water Infrastructure Limited, Gandhinagar Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Infrastructure Development Finance Company, Mumbai Management Development Institute, Gurgaon Gujarat Institute of Development Research, Ahmedabad and Maison de Suds, Bordeaux Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad National Council for Applied Economic Research, New Delhi Bentley College, Waltham, MA Delhi School of Economics and Massachusetts Institute of Technology Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Commonwealth Human Rights Initiative, Delhi Independent consultant, Mumbai Public Affairs Centre, Bangalore Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad National Institute of Urban Affairs, Delhi Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Infrastructure Development Finance Company, Mumbai Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Public Affairs Centre, Bangalore Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Steel Tubes of India, Indore Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Infrastructure Development Finance Company, Mumbai Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur Department of Economics, Kirori Mal College, Delhi Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Department of Economics, University of Mumbai Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad INDIA INFRASTRUCTURE REPORT 2002 Governance Issues for Commercialization 3iNetwork Infrastructure Development Finance Company Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur 1 PREFACE During this past year, the 3iNetwork has greatly grown in strength. Besides working on the India Infrastructure Report (IIR) 2002, the network is engaged in several projects as part of its endeavour to fulfill its mission: to bring intellectual capital to the infrastructure sector. It is heartening to see that the network has been the principal catalyst in bringing infrastructure issues to the focus for policy-analysts and researchers at various institutions. There are several studies and research projects under its programme agenda that aim to further the development of infrastructure in India, especially in the areas of power, telecom, environment, and coastal shipping. A number of theses and dissertations are being undertaken by students at IIT, Kanpur and IIM, Ahmedabad. Much of the credit for this heightened interest in infrastructure-related issues goes rightfully to the faculty members. It is also gratifying to note several professors at IIT(K) and IIM(A), who have been among the founders of the network, are contributing to the efforts by the Central and some state governments to tackle the problems of infrastructure in the country. Sidharth Sinha is a member of the Committee to Review the Orissa Reforms in the Power Sector, constituted by the Government of Orissa. S.G. Dhande has played an important role in conceptualizing the Media Lab (MIT) project in India. V.N. Asopa is carrying out a study on infrastructure support for agriculture exports. Sebastian Morris is a member of several committees reviewing power sector reforms. IIR 2002 focuses on one of the most fundamental building blocks of a reform agenda, namely, governance frameworks for commercialization. It was in December 2000 that we first mooted the subject of governance for this issue of the IIR. Subsequent developments, such as the Enron saga, the Orissa power sector reforms, delays in the introduction of the Convergence Bill, and the CNG vehicle programme in Delhi, against the backdrop of further deteriorating infrastructure services, all played a role in forcefully proving the point we had been trying to make all along—good infrastructure needs good governance. Governance should encompass the creation, protection and enforcement of certain basic rights such as rights to land, clean air, information, and to earn a livelihood. Our approach to these rights defines the framework in which our societies operate and the extent to which we can tolerate inequities and unbalanced growth of opportunities. Thus, it has implications both for welfare considerations within a country as well as at the international level. The inability to solve the problems of dispossessed peoples around the world lies at the root of international terrorism. The right to good governance in terms of policies to promote ‘public good’ arises precisely from these foundations. We ignore these fundamental issues at our own peril. What we are witnessing in India is the failure of the government to re-invent itself to meet the changing realities of our times. It was amply evident the world over that an omnipresent government attempting to do everything from maintaining law and order to providing goods and services to people, is not feasible. The business of the government is to provide good governance at least cost. This cost is the yardstick of success. The citizen comes first in any governance framework. In India, we saw the government provide services, but this came with enormous wastage of resources, deteriorating service quality, an inability to invest in improvements and safety standards, high and rising subsidies, large and unfounded pension liabilities for employees of the system, massive cost and time overruns of crucial projects, and, above all, an inability to reform encrusted institutional mechanisms that oversee this juggernaut. Many of these symptoms are illustrated in government owned and operated infrastructure services in the past such as railways, airlines, hotel and tourism services, vi Preface road building and maintenance, hospitals, and education. Clearly we need a new paradigm that will gradually dismantle what we have built since independence and replace it with an enabling environment which encourages private participation. The answer to many of our problems lies in public–private partnerships that use available resources effectively. Defining these partnerships in a manner which can be operationalized, is the challenge for the coming decade. IDFC is working on this paradigm, using UK’s Private Financing Initiative, which has enormous implications for India: privatize where possible (where commercialization possibilities exist and users of services are in a position to cover the full cost of its provision); and where this is not possible and where the government retains its accountability, to tax payers for service provision (such as education, health services, national savings, and defence), use private financing and management of services with governments paying the final bill and thereby reaping huge efficiency gains. There are many possibilities that can bridge the transition from where we are to where we wish to go. It is not the choice of means that poses a problem, as the clarity in determining the ends and setting-up objectives to be attained. This can only be done through good governance mechanisms. If one does not know to which port one is sailing, no wind is favourable. The challenge for India is to decide in which direction we wish to head. This report fulfils a gap in our understanding of governance issues for successful commercialization of infrastructure services. I am confident that IIR 2002, like its predecessor IIR 2001, will achieve widespread readership and acclaim. Nasser Munjee ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Nasser Munjee put forward the idea of governance in the context of commercializing infrastructure as a possible theme for this report at a time when the topic seemed rather nebulous to us, since few of us had the formal experience to discuss the theme. Within days though Nasser had convinced us all that most often the person or group trying to bring about the right policy is fighting bad ideas and bad decisions that then go on to become a precedent for other actions. The importance therefore of the political, institutional, organizational, economic and ideological basis of governance stands out starkly, especially in our society where there is so much visible governance failure. All of us have experienced as citizens and consumers of public services, the working of governments and its departments. We owe it to Nasser who urged us to boldly write, based on our convictions and experience. In writing we have learned much—from each other, and from ourselves—because we had to become conscious and clear about our own ideas and communicate them. As we went along we realized the enormity of the task since there was little definitive in the literature. We did not write with a particular framework, or conceptualization, or ideological standpoint. Such an approach would obviously have had the advantage of binding the report well, but would have been constraining and perhaps not true to the task of coming to grips with the problem of improving governance. We also realized that some of the more basic failures of governance are political and structural, and solutions within the current paradigm of policy may not be possible. Yet writing about them is important. The only guiding track that we followed was that our descriptions, diagnosis, and analysis ought necessarily to have the pragmatic aspect of suggesting actions and changes in policy and law, and in designing of organizations and institutions to improve governance. We appreciate and acknowledge IDFC’s support in this broad agenda. We are grateful to Partha Mukhopadhyay, Vinita Sinha, Y.M. Shivamurthy, M.Y. Rao, Ajay Narayanan, Shubhagato Dasgupta, Sri Kumar Tadimala, Vandana Bhatnagar, Saugata Bhattacharya, Anupam Srivastava, Bharati Solanki and Soumen Bagchi, for their comments and suggestions during the initial brainstorming session. The subsequent writers’ workshop to discuss the papers was held at Mussorie at the Lal Bahadur Shastri National Academy of Administration. We thank the Academy and its faculty, Binod Kumar and Y. Mathur, for their support, and Rajil Saraswat and Gaurav Shukla of the 3iNetwork at IIT(K) for the arrangements. Anupam Rastogi worked tirelessly to make these sessions fruitful. Without the remarkable dynamic scheduling of the presentations by Binayak Rath, the seminar would hardly have been possible. We owe significantly to the discussions and communications, formal and informal, we had with many people including the authors of the papers. We especially thank A.K. Mittal, Abha Singhal Joshi, Abhay Mehta, Ajay Narayanan, Ajay Pandey, Ajay Shankar, Ajit Kapadia, Alice Morris, Amita Shah, Anish Nanavaty, Anupam Rastogi, Ashok Jhunjhunwala, Ashok V. Desai, Atanu Chakraborty, Atiyah Curmally, Aurobindo Banerjee, Bernard D’Mello, Bharti Solankey, Bhavin Kothari, Biju Varkkey, Bimal Giri, Bimal Patel, Binayak Rath, Binoy Acharya, Biswajit Das, Bithin Datta, B.R. Marwah, Brian Hunter, Brij Kothari, Carol Upadhayaya, D. Subrahmanyam, Dheeraj Sanghi, Dinesh Awasthi, Errol D’Souza, G. Gopakumar, G. Raghuram, Gajendra Haldea, Gautam Navlakha, Girish Sant, H.P. Jamdar, Jahar Saha, Jaivir Singh, Jayanth Varma, Jeemol Unni, Jerome Morris, J.N. Singh, Joel Ruet, Keshab Das, K.J. Joseph, K.K. Gupta, Lokesh Garg, Mahesh Vyas, Manubhai Shah, M.H. Jowher, M.K. Iyer, M.N. Thippeswamy, Mohan Pandey, M.S. Verma, Mukesh Mathur, N. Venkiteswaran, Naishadh Parikh, Nayan Parikh, N.G. Janodia, Nirmal Mohanty, P. Panneervel, P. Bhaduri, Pakki Reddy, Pallavi Paul, P.I. Suvrathan, P.K. Taneja, Prabir Purkayastha, Praveen Kulshreshtha, Prem Kalra, Prem Pangotra, Premchander, Puneet Chitkara, R. Mohankumar, R. Ramanujam, Rakesh Basant, Rekha Jain, Sadashiv Rao, viii Acknowledgements Samir K. Barua, Sanjay Dhande, Sanjay Shah, Sanjeev Ahluwalia, Shantanu Dixit, S.K. Deshpande, Shreekant Gupta, Subodh Wagle, Sunil Parekh, T. Vijaysarathy, Tara Nair Das, T.C.A. Anant, T.K. Moullik, Trilochan Sastry, Tushaar Shah, T.V. Prabhakar, Ujwala Rajadhyakshaya, Usha Ramchandran, Venu Madhav, Venugopal Reddy, Vijay Ranchan, Vinita Sinha, Vivek Rawal, V.L. Mote, W. David Hopper, Y.M. Shivamurthy, Yudhbir, Rajil Saraswat, Gaurav Shukla and Gyan Bajpai. Ajay Pandey, S.K. Barua and Anupam Rastogi provided useful input for editing and organizing the contributions to this report.1 Sanjay Dhande and Prem Kalra must be thanked for and providing institutional support to the activities of the 3iNetwork at Kanpur and Mussoorie. T.V.S. Rammohan Rao, Dheeraj Sanghi, Rahul Varman, Puneet Chitkara and Prem Kalra also provided valuable editorial support. Mahesh Vyas went out of his way to help with the data. The entire data appendix, which we hope will be a regular and growing feature, is due entirely to his efforts. We thank him and the Centre for Monitoring the Economy for contributing to the report. Laxmi Raghavan Murali at the CMIE extracted the appendix data which Bhavin Kothari and Baidyanth Guru formatted. Urmil Anjaria virtually lived in the office ever ready to make those painful corrections on to the soft copies many times for each paper at all odd hours. Bhavin Kothari, Deepa Keskhani, Trupti Patel, Baidyanath Guru helped as assistants at IIM(A). Jaya Singhania, Gracinda Rodrigues and Babu Nambiar at IDFC helped with the coordinaton. We cannot thank them adequately for their tireless efforts. To Kavita Iyengar and Shreemoyee Patra of Oxford University Press we owe our heartfelt thanks, not only for working with a very tight schedule, but also for their valuable comments and suggestions that helped us organize the report better. On behalf of all the contributors, we thank all those who have helped us put together this report. However, we as editors are responsible for any errors that remain. Sebastian Morris Rajiv Shekhar 1 To Jahar Saha I owe a most personal thanks, for reposing the confidence he did in me and encouraging us at IIM(A). (S.M.) CONTENTS List of Tables List of Boxes and Figures List of Abbreviations and Acronyms 1. xiv xvi xviii OVERVIEW Sebastian Morris 1 Challenges for Governance and Policy-making 1 • An Opportunity for Change 2 • Good Governance in an Inequitious Society 3 • Displacement, Resettlement, Rehabilitation and the Land Constraint 3 • The Constitutional and Legal Framework 5 • Access to Information 6 • Environmental Pollution 7 • Contextualizing Regulatory Choices 8 • Corruption and Bribery 8 • Accounting for Transparency 9 • Lessons from Governance Failures 9 • Rural Poverty, Infrastructure and Gyandoot 9 • The Urban Situation 10 • Urban Water 11 • Developments in the Electricity Sector 11 • Transport 12 • Technology Moves as Consumers Wait for WLL (Telecom Sector) 13 • ‘Voice’ Governance and Networking 14 2. THE CHALLENGE Sebastian Morris TO GOVERNANCE IN INDIA 15 Institutions, Economic Development and Governance in India 20 • Mode of Subsidization and Corruption 23 • Shortages and Corruption 27 • Contracts Regulation and Governance 30 • Conclusion 34 References 35 3. THE INFRASTRUCTURE SECTOR 3.1 IN INDIA, 2000–1 37 A Review of Sectors 37 Anupam B. Rastogi Highlights 37 • Initiatives at the State Level 39 • Power and Energy 39 • Power Sector Reforms and States 42 • Other Sectors 45 • Conclusion 53 3.2 WLL, Governance, Corporatization and SWANS: A Review of Institutional Developments 54 Rekha Jain State Wide Area Networks for Governance 56 • Creation of VSNL 57 • Convergence Bill Highlights 59 • Major Functions of the Regulatory Commission 59 References 59 4. THE CONSTITUTIONAL 4.1 AND LEGAL FRAMEWORK FOR GOVERNANCE The Framework of Regulation 60 T.C.A. Anant and Jaivir Singh Instruments of Regulation 61 • Governance Structures: Legislature, Executive and Judiciary 63 60 x Contents 4.2 How Public Feedback Aids Public Accountability 66 Samuel Paul and Gopakumar K. The Disabling Environment of Public Services 66 • Exploring the Potency of ‘Voice’ Through Report Cards 68 • Evaluating and Benchmarking Civil Services in Bangalore 68 • Developing Ward Based Indicators in Mumbai 70 • Business Environment in Karnataka 71 • Creating Public Awareness 72 • Stimulating Agency Reforms 72 • Strengthening Civil Society Initiatives 72 • Democratic Responsiveness 73 • Critical Success Factors 73 • Conclusion 74 4.3 The Legal Framework for Private Participation 74 Piush Joshi and R.V. Anuradha Constitutional Provisions 74 • Essential Features of the Legal Framework 75 • A Critique of the Legal Framework for Private Participation 77 • Contractual Framework 79 • Uniform Law for Infrastructure Projects 80 • Gujarat BOT Law 82 4.4 Opening Doors to ‘the Outsiders’: The Right to Information 83 Abha Singhal Joshi Right to Information Laws Elsewhere 84 • Obligation to Publish in Acts of Certain States 86 • Procedures for Obtaining Information Ignored 86 • Godbole’s Critique 88 • World Bank’s Push for Transparency 88 • Using the Right to Information 89 • The MKSS Experience 89 4.5 Community Participation Makes a Difference: Water and Sanitation Projects in Rural India 90 S. Manikutty Findings 90 • Impact on Project Outcomes 92 • Conclusion 94 References 94 5. ENVIRONMENT 5.1 AND REHABILITATION Environmental Governance and Regulation in India 96 Atiyah Curmally Legislative Efforts 96 • The Prevailing Form of Governance 98 • Perverse Incentives under CAC 100 • Suggestions to Facilitate More Effective Regulation 101 5.2 The Assault on Workers in Land Use Policy and Practice in Delhi 108 Delhi Janwadi Adhikar Manch The Legal Context 109 • The High Price of Survival 114 • The Struggle Over Urban Space 115 5.3 Railway Slums in Mumbai 119 Prem K. Kalra and P. Nandini Kumar Genesis of the Mumbai Slums 119 • The Story so Far 121 5.4 Power Projects Development: Review of Social and Environmental Issues 121 Binayak Rath and K. Ramakrishnan Issues in the Development of Power Projects 122 • Mitigation Measures 123 • Building a Framework for R&R 124 • Recommendations for Effective R&R 124 5.5 The CNG Vehicles Programme in Delhi 125 B.P. Pundir CNG in Delhi 126 • Supply Infrastructure 127 • Challenges 128 • Conclusions 129 5.6 Environmental Impacts of Large Dams: A Social Critique 130 Bernard D’Mello The Narmada Campaign and PIL 130 • EIAs and SIAs 132 • Conclusion 134 References 136 96 Contents 6. REGULATORY 6.1 AND CONTRACTUAL FRAMEWORK xi 138 Private Finance to Private Entrepreneurship 138 Jayanth R. Varma Market-driven Resource Allocation 138 • Reasons for the Emergence of the Current Model 139 • The Way Forward 140 • Excessive and Premature Regulation 144 • Pro-competitive Regulation 146 • Strategic Infrastructure Projects 146 • Conclusions 148 6.2 The Gujarat Gas Bill and Its Genesis 148 Atanu Chakraborty Antecedents 148 • Features of the Gas Act 149 6.3 Corruption and Governance: Insights from the Literature 150 Ajay Pandey Economic Analysis of Corruption and Evidence 151 • Infrastructure Sectors and Corruption 157 6.4 Accrual Accounting for Infrastructure Assets: A Review 159 Mahender Gujarathi and Samir K. Barua Accounting Standards for Infrastructure 160 • Rationale and Soundness of the GASB 34 Provisions 161 • Accrual Accounting: A Square Peg in a Round Hole? 161 • Conclusions 163 6.5 Crises in the Governance of Financial Infrastructure 164 Samir K. Barua Financial Infrastructure: A Brief Overview 164 • The Securities Scam of 1992 165 • MMCB Scam 168 • US-64 Crisis 169 • Lessons from the Scams 171 • Summary 174 6.6 Is Bribery Welfare-promoting? 174 Praveen Kulshreshtha A Basic Framework of Rationing-by-Waiting 175 • Rationing-by-Waiting in the Presence of Bribery: Efficiency and Welfare Implications 176 • Conclusion 177 6.7 The Enron Disaster 179 Prayas Energy Group The Malady 179 • The Remedy 182 • Conclusion 184 References 185 7. RURAL INFRASTRUCTURE 7.1 Endowments and Rural Infrastructure: Issues Today 187 Keshab Das Planning and the Rural Sector 187 • Chronic Rural Poverty: The Bitter Reality 189 • State or Market 190 • Sanitation Facilities 190 • Drinking Water Supply 191 • Roads 192 • Housing 193 7.2 Transforming Gujarat Villages into Gokul Grams: Can it Happen? 195 Keshab Das The Idea 195 • Little Community Participation 197 7.3 Gyandoot: Can it be the Harbinger of Knowledge? 198 Brij Kothari, Avinash Pandey and Amita Chudgar Investment 199 • Control over Soochanalayas 199 • The Gyandoot Software 200 • Service Charges 200 • Observations 202 • Feedback 203 • Conclusion 204 References 205 187 xii Contents 8. URBAN INFRASTRUCTURE 8.1 206 Management of Infrastructure Projects in Urban Local Bodies: Case Study of Kanpur Development Authority 206 Bithin Datta The Kanpur Development Authority 206 • Procedure for Planning and Implementation 207 • Problems in Planning 208 • Problems in Implementation 209 • Private Participation 210 • Encouraging Signals at KDA 211 8.2 Transfer of Development Rights: An Alternative to Conventional Land Acquisition 212 Bhavin Kothari Transfer of Development Rights (TDR) 212 • TDRs in Mumbai 213 8.3 Issues in Municipal Water Supply: A Case Study of Kanpur 214 Mukesh Sharma Current Water Pricing 214 • Water Losses and Revenue Collection 215 • Pumping and Water Treatment 216 8.4 Water Reforms through Water Markets: International Experience and Issues for India 217 Nirmal Mohanty and Shreekant Gupta Water Markets and their Rationale 217 • International Experience with Water Markets 219 • Water Markets in India 221 • Introducing Formal Water Markets in India 222 • Conclusion 225 8.5 Alandur Sewerage Project: A Unique Experiment of Public Participation in Project Financing 226 Mukesh P. Mathur Project Particulars 226 • Project Cost and Finance 227 • Public Participation 228 • Project Status on March 2001 229 8.6 SWM and Scope of Peoples’ Participation: A Case Study Of Kanpur Nagar Nigam 229 Binayak Rath Solid Waste in India 229 • Government Policies 230 • Management of Solid Waste in Kanpur 231 • Abortive Attempts at Change 234 • Bringing in the Informal Sector 235 References 236 9. FRAMEWORK 9.1 FOR THE ENERGY SECTOR 238 Regulatory Objectives, Processes, and Outcomes: First Power Tariff Norms 238 Ajay Pandey Issues in the Consultation Paper 240 • Consultant’s Reports on Rate of Return, Depreciation and O&M Costs 241 • CERC’s Order on Tariff Norms 244 • On Process and Outcome 248 9.2 Inter-state Transmission of Electricity: Lessons from the Northern Regional Grid Collapse 249 Puneet Chitkara, Rajiv Shekhar and Prem K. Kalra The Collapse 249 • Reliable Transmission 251 • Responding Swiftly to Emergencies 253 • Maintenance and Monitoring 253 • Communication 254 • Power Quality 254 • Transmission Ownership 256 9.3 Orissa Power Sector Reforms: Getting Back on Track 260 Sidharth Sinha Tariff Setting and T&D Losses 262 • Privatization of Distribution 264 • Performance of Privatized DISTCOs 266 • GRIDCO’s Financial Performance 267 • Role of Government in the Reform Process 268 • Getting Back on Track 269 9.4 Power Sector Reforms and Proposed Electricity Bill 271 Ajay Pandey Draft Electricity Bill, 2001 272 • Proposed Bill and the NCAER Draft 275 • Power Sector and Electricity Bill, 2001: An Assessment 276 Contents xiii 9.5 Oil and Gas Contracts: Lessons from Mukta–Panna Oil Fields 277 T.V.S. Ramamohan Rao, Puneet Chitkara, and Kaushal K. Saxena The Background for Re-structuring 277 • Emergence of a New Organizational Structure 278 • New Exploration Licensing Policy 279 • Model Production Sharing Contract 280 • The Mukta– Panna Contract 282 • Lessons and Recommendations 285 References 287 10. INTEGRATED TRANSPORT 288 10.1 Experiences of Various Forms of Commercial Partnerships in Indian Railways 288 G. Raghuram Container Corporation of India 288 • Palace on Wheels 289 • Railway Sidings 290 • Piplav Railway Corporation Limited 291 • Konkan Railway Corporation 292 • Ro-Ro Services on Konkan Railway 292 • Own Your Wagon Scheme 293 • Catering Contracts 294 • Conclusion 294 10.2 Civil Aviation in India: Deregulation and Constraints to Growth and Efficiency 296 Subir Gokarn Impact of Partial Liberalization 296 • Airports 297 10.3 State Road Transport Undertakings in India: Issues, Constraints and Options 300 S. Sriraman 10.4 Governance Issues in Airport Development: Learnings from Cochin International Airport Ltd 303 Biju Varkkey and G. Raghuram The CIAL Experience 303 • Implications for Governance 310 References 312 11. TELECOMMUNICATIONS 313 11.1 Untangling Wireless in Local Loops 313 Rekha Jain and Dheeraj Sanghi TRAI’s Recommendations 313 • Incumbents and Regulatory Agencies 315 • Spectrum Management 316 • Is WLL Really an Extension of Basic Service? 317 11.2 Spectrum Allocations in India 318 Sidharth Sinha 11.3 Telecom Regulation and Internet Telephony 323 Dheeraj Sanghi Technology 324 • Current Regulatory Model and Internet Telephony 325 • Regulating Internet Telephony 327 • Conclusion 328 11.4 State Wide Area Networks: The First Initiatives 328 Rekha Jain and G. Raghuram APSWAN 329 • GSWAN 329 • RSVAN 329 • WBSWAN 331 • A Preliminary Assessment 331 11.5 Mergers and Acquisitions in the Indian Telecom 332 Lokesh Garg and Venu Madhav Award of Licences 332 • Consolidation 333 • Value Drivers for Indian Telecom M&As 334 • Conclusion 337 References 337 STATISTICAL APPENDIX 338 TABLES 3.1.1 3.1.2 3.1.3 3.2.1 4.2.1 4.2.2 4.2.3 4.2.4 4.2.5 4.2.6 4.2.7 4.2.8 4.3.1 4.5.1 4.5.2 5.2.1 5.2.2 5.5.1 5.5.2 5.5.3 6.7.1 7.1.1 7.1.2 7.1.3 7.1.4 7.1.5 7.2.1 7.2.2 8.1.1 8.1.2 8.2.1 8.2.2 8.3.1 8.3.2 8.3.3 8.5.1 Sanctions and Disbursements of Major DFIs Power Sector ‘Reforms’: A ‘Score Card’ for States Some Examples of Infrastructure Initiative Funds (IIFs) Comparison of Telecom Indicators in Different Countries Overall Satisfaction with Public Agencies in Bangalore (General Households), 1993 Bribes Paid to Various Agencies in Bangalore, 1993 Satisfaction of Users in Interactions with Public Agencies/Service Providers in Bangalore Bribes Paid to Various Agencies in Bangalore, 1994 and 1999 Availability, Usage and Satisfaction with Pubic Services in Mumbai, (per cent), 1998 Reasons for Dissatisfaction Among Urban Poor in Mumbai with Regard to Certain Services, 1998 Ranking of Disabling Factors in Karnataka’s Industrial Environment Satisfaction of Medium Scale Investors in Karnataka Distribution of Activities in Accordance with the Seventh Schedule and Article 246 of the Constitution Community Participation Index in Certain States Outcomes With and Without CP Land Use Pattern Proposed by MPD Area Under Squatter Settlement in Delhi CNG Vehicles in Delhi CNG Filling Stations in Delhi Emission Potential of Engines TAPing the Three Main Governance Agencies Dimensions of Poverty and Inequality in Rural India, 1973–2000 Sanitation Facilities in Rural India, 1985–99 Sources of Drinking Water in Inhabited Villages in India Profile of Housing Loans advanced by GRUH Finance Ltd Agricultural Workers in Rural India, 1951–91 Villages Targeted Under GGY Works Completed Under GGY, 1995–2000 Annual Income of KDA Annual Expenditure of KDA TDR Programmes at Various Urban Centres TDRs in Mumbai Salient Data on Municipal Water Supply in Mumbai Tax Valuation and Size of Connection Water Charges as Share of Income Basic Information on Alandur 38 43 53 58 69 69 70 70 71 71 72 72 82 90 93 116 117 127 127 128 184 189 190 192 194 195 197 197 207 207 213 214 214 215 216 226 List of Tables 8.5.2 8.5.3 8.5.4 8.6.1 8.6.2 9.3.1 9.3.2 9.3.3 9.3.4 9.3.5 10.1.1 10.1.2 10.1.3 10.3.1 10.3.2 10.3.3 10.3.4 10.4.1 10.4.2 10.4.3 11.5.1 11.5.2 Project Costs Sources of Project Finance One-time Connection Deposits Waste Generation in India Waste Generation and Collection in Kanpur Retail Tariff Increases T&D Losses: Proposed and Approved Financial Performance of DISTCOs (2000–1) Details of Collection of DISTCOs Distribution Losses Stake of the Indian Railways Performance of Ro-Ro Services Attributes of Commercialization by the Railways Magnitude of Profits and Losses, 1999–2000 Recovery–Cost Trends Haryana Roadways: Share of Private Sector Performance of Haryana Roadways Initial Financing Plan (1992) Project Cost Capital Structure Cellular Licences in Certain Countries M&A Deals in the Indian Telecom Sector, c. 2001 and Earlier xv 217 228 228 230 232 262 263 265 265 266 288 293 295 300 300 301 302 304 304 310 333 333 BOXES AND FIGURES BOXES 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 3.1.1 3.1.2 3.1.3 3.1.4 4.2.1 4.3.1 4.4.1 4.4.2 5.1.1 5.1.2 5.2.1 5.2.2 5.2.3 5.2.4 5.2.5 5.5.1 5.6.1 6.1.1 6.1.2 6.1.3 6.3.1 6.5.1 6.7.1 8.1.1 8.3.1 8.5.1 9.2.1 9.2.2 9.2.3 States, Governance, and Industrialization: A Historical Review Corruption in China Institutional Efforts for PSU Management Fail Creating Governance Failure in the Oil Sector The Indian Experience The Tragedy of Indian Administration Infrastructure Sector in the Report of the PM’s Economic Advisory Council The Central Road Fund The Rakesh Mohan Committee Report The Sukthankar Committee Report Making an Informed Choice Legal Framework in Electricity, Telecom, and National Highways The Freedom of Information Bill Information and Atomic Programmes GBUS: Greens See Red Over Project Clearance Norm Changes The Politics of Pollution Industrial Closures in Delhi Restructuring the City Evictions Who are the Land Grabbers? Life at Relocation Sites NGV Programmes Elsewhere ‘Large Dams: Indian’s Experience Standard Times in Nineteenth Century United States Right of Way for US Railroads Oil Pipelines in Nineteenth Century United States Why Governance Matters: A World Bank Perspective SEBI Report: A Damp Squib The Godbole Committee’s Findings Failed Housing Projects Composition of UFW Willingness to Pay Why Does the Grid collapse Other Grid Accidents in 2000 Dynamic Line-Rating System 17 18 22 24 29 31 40 46 49 51 73 76 84 87 105 106 110 112 113 117 118 126 135 141 141 142 152 173 180 208 215 229 250 250 252 List of Figures and Boxes 9.2.4 9.2.5 9.2.6 9.3.1 9.5.1 9.5.2 9.5.3 9.5.4 10.2.1 11.2.1 11.2.2 11.2.3 11.4.1 xvii Intelligent Systems and Condition Monitoring Power Factor versus Displacement Power Factor Issues for Transmission Management related to ABT Measurement of T&D Losses Functions of the DGH Ravva Fields Contract Enron selling its stake Public Interest Litigation Regulatory Institutions in Civil Aviation in India Spectrum Management in India Recommendations of Spectrum Management Committee, Steering Group of the WPC and TRAI Issues in Spectrum Licensing Precursors to SWANs 255 256 260 263 280 282 283 284 299 318 319 321 330 Illustrative Contractual Framework: Power Project Gujarat Gas Act: The Actors and Relationship P ≥ V/b P < V/b P ≥ V/b P < V/b Hutchison’s Footprint in the Indian Cellular Market after the Fourth Round of Licensing Bharti’s Footprint in the Indian Cellular Market after the Fourth Round of Licensing BATATA-BPL’s Footprint in the Indian Cellular Market after the Fourth Round of Licensing Reliance Telecom’s Footprint in the Indian Cellular Market after the Fourth Round of Licensing Four Layer Structure of Communication under Convergence 81 149 177 177 178 178 335 335 335 335 336 FIGURES 4.3.1 6.2.1 6.6.1 6.6.2 6.6.3 6.6.4 11.5.1 11.5.2 11.5.3 11.5.4 11.5.5 ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS ABT ABTO AERA AM APERC APIIF APTransco APTS ASP BARC BBMB BBUL BCAS BHEL BOD BPCB BPCL BSES BSO BT BWSSB CAA CAPM CARD CDMA CDSL CEA CERC CESCO CESL CETP CMS CMWSSB CNFSTT CNS/ATM COAI availability based tariff (of the CERC) Association of Basic Telecom Operators Airports Economic Regulatory Authority Alandur Municipality Andhra Pradesh Electricity Regulatory Commission Andhra Pradesh Infrastructure Initiative Funds Andhra Pradesh Transmission Company AP Technology Services Alandur Sewerage Project Bhabha Atomic Research Centre Bhakra–Beas Management Board Bharat Bari Udyog Limited Bureau of Civil Aviation Security Bharat Heavy Electricals Ltd biological oxygen demand Bihar Pollution Control Board Bharat Petroleum Corporation Limited Bombay Suburban Electricity Supply Company basic service operator British Telecom Bangalore Water and Sewerage Services Board Civil Aviation Authority (of India) capital asset pricing model Computer-Aided Administration of Registration Department code division multiple access Central Depository for Securities Limited Central Electricity Authority Central Electricity Regulatory Commission Central Electricity Supply Company (in Orissa) Consulting Engineering Services Limited common effluent treatment plant cellular mobile services Chennai Metropolitan Water Supply and Sewerage Board curtailable non-firm short-term transaction communication, navigation, surveillance, air traffic management Cellular Operators Association of India Abbreviations and Acronyms CONCOR CRTC CSJ CTU CWCL CWSE DANIDA DBEC DCA DECT DEL DFID DGA DGCA DGH DLD DOA DoT DPC DPCC DPF DPS DRDA DSL DST DTO DTS DVB ELD EMS EOGIL EPCA ERCA ERG ESA FACTS FASB FAST FFUIDC FIPB FM FRP FSI FSP FSTT GAIL GAP GASB GEB GIDA GIDB GMB Container Corporation of India Canadian Radio-television and Telecommunication Commission Centre for Social Justice central transmission utility Central Warehousing Corporation Limited City Water and Sewage Establishment Danish International Development Assistance Dakshin Bharat Energy Consortium Department of Companies Affairs digital enhanced cordless technology direct exchange line Department for International Development dissolved gas analysis Director General of Civil Aviation Directorate General of Hydrocarbons domestic long distance distribution operations agreement Department of Telecom Dhabol Power Corporation Delhi Pollution Control Committee displacement power factor delayed payment surcharge District Rural Development Agency digital subscriber loop Department of Science and Technology Department of Telecom Operations Department of Telecom Services Delhi Vidyut Board economic load dispatch problem energy management system Enron Oil and Gas India Limited Environment Pollution (Prevention & Control) Authority Electricity Regulatory Commissions Act eastern region grid Electricity Supply Act flexible AC transmission system Financial Accounting Standards Board fully automated services of transport Feedback Finance Urban Infrastructure Development Company Foreign Investment Promotion Board frequency modulation financial reconstructing plan floor space index fixed service providers firm short term transactions Gas Authority of India Ltd Ganga Action Plan Government Accounting Standards Board Gujarat Electricity Board Gujarat Infrastructure Development Act Gujarat Industrial Development Board Gujarat Maritime Board xix xx Abbreviations and Acronyms GOG GOPL GOT GPPL GRIDCO GRPS GSM GSPC GSPL GSWAN GTE HFCL HPCL HSD HSE HUDCO HVDC IASC IBRD ICAO ICD ICF ICI ICICI ICOLD ICRA ICT IEA IEGC IIF IIP ILD ILS IOC IPP IPSAS IRDP IRFC ISTS IWAI JNPT JPC JTG KDA KEB KIAS KNN KPTCL KRC KSEB KWA LEC Government of Gujarat Gujarat Online Private Limited group on telecommunication Gujarat Pipavav Port Limited Grid Corporation of Orissa general pocket radio services group special mobile Gujarat State Petroleum Corporation Gujarat State Petronet Ltd Gujarat State Wide Area Networks government trading enterprises Hindustan Futuristic Communication Limited Hindustan Petroleum Company Limited high speed diesel Harmonic State Estimation Housing and Urban Development Corporation high voltage direct current International Accounting Standards Committee International Bank for Reconstruction and Development International Civil Aviation Organisation Internal Container Depot Integral Coach Factory Imperial Chemical Industries Industrial Credit and Investment Corporation of India International Commission on Large Dams Investment and Credit Rating Agency Information and Communication Technology Indian Elecctricity Act Indian Electricity Grid Code Infrastructure Initiative Fund index of industrial production (of India) international long distance instrument landing system Indian Oil Corporation independent power producer International Public Sector Accounting Standards Integrated Rural Development Programme Indian Railway Finance Corporation Inter State Transmission System Indian Waterways Authority of India Jawharlal Nehru Port Trust Joint Parliamentary Committee Joint Telematics Group Kanpur Development Authority Karnataka Electricity Board Kochi International Airport Society Kanpur Nagar Nigam Karnataka Power Transmission Corporation Ltd Konkan Railway Corporation Karnataka State Electricity Board Kerala Water Authority local exchange carriers Abbreviations and Acronyms MBI MbPT MERC MGRA MJP MKSS MMC MMCB MNA MNES MNP MOEF MPFI MPSC MRTPC MSEB MTNL MUTP-II MRVC NABARD NATPAC NBA NCA NELP NESCO NFAP NHAI NHB NHDP NHP NHPC NLC NLDC NOC NREP NRG NRLDC NSDF NSDL NSE NSSO NTP NTPC NWDT ODRC OERC OHPC OIDB OIL ONGC OPF OPGC market-based instrument Mumbai Port Trust Maharashtra Electricity Regulatory Commission Maharastra Groundwater Regulatory Authority Maharashtra Jeevan Pradhikaran Mazdoor Kisan Shakti Sanagathan Monopolies and Mergers Commission Madhavpura Mercantile Cooperative Bank Mukhya Nagar Adhikari Ministry of Non-conventional Energy Sources minimum needs programme Ministry of Environment and Forest Multi-point fuel injection Model production sharing contract Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Commission Maharashtra State Electricity Board Mahanagar Telephone Nigam Limited Mumbai Urban Transport Project -II Mumbai Rail Vikas Corporation National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development National Transport Planning and Research Centre Narmada Bachao Andolan Narmada Control Authority New Exploration Licensing Policy Northern Elctricity Supply Coportation national frequency allocation plan National Highway Authority of India National Housing Bank National Highway Development Plan National Housing Policy National Hydroelectric Power Corporation Neyveli Lignite Corporation National Load Dispatch Centre National Oil Companies National Rural Employment Programme Northern Region Grid Northern Region Load Dispatch Centre National Slum Dwellers’ Federation National Security Depository Limited National Stock Exchange National Sample Survey Organisation National Telecom Policy (1994 and 1999) National Thermal Power Corporation Narmada Water Disputes Tribunal optimized depreciation replacement cost Orissa Electricity Regulatory Commission Orissa Hydro Power Corporation Oil Industry Development Board Oil India Limited Oil and Natural Gas Commission optimal power flow Orissa Power Generation Company xxi xxii Abbreviations and Acronyms OSEB OYW PCM PDC PET PETP PFC PGCIL PIB pkm PLF PMS POL POSCO PPA PRA PRCL PROPER PSC PSCoT PSM PSTN PUC Puhca PVC RAC RBO REB REC REDA RIAP RKS RLEGP RNFC RSDF RSP RTDC RTPS RWSS SACFA SCADA SDCA SEBI SEC SENSEX SERC SIL SLDC SMC SOC SOQ SOS Orissa State Electricity Board Own Your Wagon (Scheme) of the Indian Railways pulse code modulation project development company polyethylene terephthalate primary effluent treatment plant Power Finance Corporation Power Grid Corporation of India Limited Project Implementation Board passenger kilometres plant load factor Portfolio Management Scheme petroleum, oil, and lubricants Pohang Steel of South Korea power purchase agreement participatory rural appraisal Pipavav Railway Corporation Limited Program for Pollution Control, Evaluation and Rating Production Sharing Contract Parliamentary Standing Committee on Telecommunications payment security mechanism public switched telecom network pollution under control (certification) Public Utility Holding Companies Act. poly-vinyl chloride regional advisory committees river basin organization Regional Electricity Board Rural Electrification Corporation Renewable Energy Development Authority revenue improvement action plan Rationing Kruti Samiti Rural Landless Employment Guarantee Programme route navigation facility charge Railway Slum Dwellers’ Federation rural service provider Rajasthan Tourism Development Corporation Raichur Thermal Power Station Rural Water Supply and Sanitation State Advisory Committee on Radio Frequency Allocation Supervisory Control and Data Acquisition short distance calling area Security and Exchange Board of India Securities Exchange Commission Sensitive Index of the Bombay Stock Exchange State Electricity Regulatory Commission surge impedance loading state load dispatch center Spectrum Management Committee specific oil consumption statement of qualification strategic operation study Abbreviations and Acronyms SOUTHCO SPV SRG STP STPS SWERF TAMP TAXES TC TDRs TDSAT TIL TNEB TNUDP TRA TRAI TRYSEM TWINS UDPFI UGS UHRA UPS UPSRTC USHDT VHF FM VPN VSAT VSNL WARP WCD WEBEL WESCO WLL(LM) WPC WRG WWC Southern Electricity Supply Corporation special purpose vehicle Southern Region Grid sewerage treatment plant Super Thermal Power Station solid waste energy recycling facility Tariff Authority for Major Ports trunk automatic exchanges taluka centre transfer of development rights Telecom Dispute Settlement and Appellate Tribunal Tata Infotech Limited Tamil Nadu Electricity Board Tamil Nadu Urban Development Project trust retention account agreement Telecom Regulatory Authority of India Training of Rural Youth for Self Employment Twin Cities Network Project Urban Development Plan Formulation and Implemention Underground Sewerage Scheme Upstream Hydrocarbon Regulatory Authority uninterrupted power supply UP State Road Transport Corporation US heavy duty transient test cycle very high frequency (frequency modulation) virtual private networks very small aperture terminal Videsh Sanchar Nigam Ltd Watch Your Ward Program World Commission on Dams West Bengal Electronics Development Corporation Western Electricity Supply Corporation Wireless in Local Loop with Limited Mobility Wireless Planning and Coordination Western Region Grid Ward Water Committees xxiii Overview 1 1 OVERVIEW Sebastian Morris CHALLENGES FOR GOVERNANCE POLICY-MAKING AND The liberalization of the early 1990s, if it is to prove anything more than episodic raising of expectations, has to ensure high growth for several decades to come. In Chapter 2 it is argued that while conservative economic policy including tame pricing of the currency has brought about recession, continued fiscal conservatism deepens it. The more recent downward pressure on consumer expenditures in the US following already existing recessionary conditions can be expected to put a brake on world expenditures1 and hence bring world down incomes. This spells difficult times for India, already in the midst of an industrial recession. The scope of increasing demand through monetary expansion which was there until the latter part of 1998, is now most certainly absent. Nothing short of a fairly large fiscal boost accompanied by a relative decline in the real value of the rupee will work. The current fall in the value of the rupee against the dollar needs to be actively accelerated, since in the world economy with shrinking demand, India must try to match the structurally undervalued currencies of China and the East Asian economies. The currency crisis has pushed the already structurally undervalued currencies of Thailand, Korea and Taiwan even further down. This is not the time for ideological histrionics. The undue fear of fiscal deficit and inflation has to be overcome. With an expenditure multiplier of around two and half over the year, and a tax to GDP elasticity much in excess of one, the danger of a ballooning fiscal deficit with some (controlled) boost in government expenditures is greatly exaggerated. In any case, the industrial sector, more than others, is in deep 1 Unless the war results in major expenditure increases. recession. Taxes have a large base in industrial output, and it is industrial output that would rise steeply with a fiscal boost. Consequently, the fiscal position of the government would not deteriorate much. The need of the hour is therefore a coordinated fiscal and monetary expansion with a sharp depreciation of the currency2 and major and quick reform of infrastructure policies especially in the power sector to draw in private investment once the economy restarts and the private sector needs to meet demand. Unfortunately the move in that direction by the Prime Minister’s office has been watered down by conservative economists who currently monopolize macroeconomic policy-making, both within the government and the RBI. They refuse to recognize that the limits to reducing the fiscal deficit via active reduction of the primary fiscal deficit have long been reached, probably by the end of 1999–2000. The only realistic measure now is to grow out of the fiscal deficit, and (in a smaller way) inflate away part of the debt. The faster this begins the better it would be for the economy. The task of pursuing high growth without bringing about fiscal crisis is the first challenge today. The large buffer stocks of food also ought to bolster confidence to increase fiscal expenditures. There is, of course, the fear of fiscal boost bringing in wastage inherent in government expenditure. This is true even in the case of investment expenditures. The fear is shared even by those of a more Keynesian persuasion. Despite this, unless the economy is lifted up in the next year or so there is a very high chance that benefits from the reforms so far are lost. As support for reforms vanishes among the industrialists and the poor, who have to face the situation of stagnancy or decline in the 2 Instead of waiting for speculators to beat it down. 2 India Infrastructure Report 2002 number of jobs, the danger of a political backlash and the end of privatization is real. Many structural reforms, awaiting the scope that is there in a growing economy may be lost for another decade at least. These are reforms in the labour markets, administration of subsidies and introduction of user charges in many publicly provided goods. The opportunity to bring about changes in subsidy administration in electricity, water, food, fertilizer and fuel was never better. Chapter 2 outlines the vast benefits in right administration through direct subsidies. Most importantly, it would cut the Gordian knot that has hindered, true reform in water and electricity. Here it is important to recognize that the mountains of food could be turned into infrastructure, alleviating hunger and poverty if the right structure of administration and governance for an efficient and productive food for work programme could be found. (The starting point really is direct subsidization). This is the second challenge today. If met, it has the potential of making policy, organizational development, and governance itself the leverage points of change. In IIR 2001, it was emphasized that the demand (depressionary) effects of declining infrastructural investments had been one of the reasons for the slower growth of the economy as a whole. Budgetary cuts on public investments which largely hurt physical infrastructure like power and irrigation, in so far as their expenditure effects were concerned, had been more than compensated by the rising private investments in manufacturing which continued right up to 1995–6. The only way private investment could have kept its higher pace of growth would have been through infrastructure investments. But lack of regulatory clarity and policy risks kept the private sector away. The problem continues perhaps with even more severe depressionary effect. Since then, important positive developments have come about but they are not adequate to bring large-scale private entry into infrastructure. The notable achievement, as Anupam Rastogi brings out in Chapter 3, has been the creation of a road fund and the commitment of the government to complete and modernize the golden quadrilateral and the north-south and east-west corridors. The Draft Bill on Electricity although in the right direction of open access and towards a market for generation, has many problems that are brought out by Ajay Pandey in Section 9.4. The bill while necessary, given the inevitability of the decentralized and plural mode of the electricity system, is not adequate by itself. Unless the problem of cross subsidy and agency failure that it creates in distribution entities, whether public or private, is overcome via direct subsidization, private investments would not flow into the sector. In the telecom sector after National Telecom Policy, 1999 (NTP 99) and the promise of the convergence bill, the retrograde step of wireless in local loop (WLL) and the limited mobility WLL that followed, while restoring a fair equilibrium between the players in the industry is patently against the consumer interest. Denying the technological benefits of WLL via code division multiple access (CDMA), group special mobile (GSM) or corDECT (DECT of Tenet Corporation) is not right at this juncture when the network (given network economies) is poised to expand rapidly. These developments apart, there is little that has taken place along the direction of bringing about regulatory and policy clarity that was highlighted in the previous issue. Why have developments been so weak or slow? Closer examination shows that the working of the government particularly in its detailed policy, rule and law making roles has been maimed by inadequate skills, knowledge and activism, and perhaps most by the systemic ills which we discuss in Chapter 2 in a generic fashion and cover in many of the papers in specific contexts. Besides competency, the power of vested interests, graft and corruption, and turf wars between specialist catalyst organizations like the Gujarat Infrastructural Development Board (GIDB) and the rest of the governmental system have been responsible. The third challenge today is therefore to improve the governance of economic institutions, be it the financial sector, industrial development boards or courts dealing with economic issues. It is a challenge of governance in the usual sense of the term. And much of this report is concerned with that task i.e. the challenge of governance in the context of commercializing infrastructure. At its core this task is one of better design, writing better contracts, bringing clearer, and transparent rules, avoidance of internal contradictions in policy and laws. It also means right manning of key regulatory and governance institutions, better and appropriate incentive structures, and working with newer and potent institutions and laws that bring in the citizen and the consumer into governance as a participant, evaluator and user. AN OPPORTUNITY FOR CHANGE Liberalization, precisely because it succeeded in the sense of creating a more open and market oriented economy, has resulted in the present situation, where the three challenges mentioned earlier arise and need to be overcome. The first is a challenge for economic policy, the second for both policy and organizational development and governance, and the third is essentially a challenge of governance. Policymakers and people with the power to take decisions are today in the enviable position of having a particular autonomy. But this window of opportunity is narrow and the constraints will soon reassert to deny any leeway. More usually, the scope of decision making is limited to the small decisions that help to maintain the system and any attempt at bold decisions to make significant change is usually Overview 3 frustrated. But today there is a difference. Politically and in an economic sense the moment is right to take the big decisions that would change the course of the economy and the society for many years to come. In other words we are at the crossroads and there is autonomy for action. Such opportunities have been few and far between. The period immediately after independence, the period following the crisis of the late sixties, the year after the second oil shock, and the crisis year of 1991–2 have provided such opportunities in the past. Our economy and society is what it is today because of the particular decisions that were taken (or avoided) then. Unfortunately we do not see a coherent response to the situation today. As already mentioned, the bind of orthodoxy on the economy has been particularly severe. The costs of learning imposed by the Reserve Bank of India (RBI), the Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI) and the electricity regulators and policy makers have been onerous. There is no discussion as yet on the opportunity and need to right structure subsidy administration, not even in the crucial electricity sector. Neither is there the appreciation that transparency (necessary in commercialization and privatization) would demand that ‘clever’ sections inserted by the bureaucracy do not take back the power that is ‘granted’ in the very same law to the independent regulator. The problems of governance today are severe and solutions are not easy. The task is really to go under the skin of the general tenets of transparency, accountability and consumer interest (and often participation of citizens), to be able to say how these can be brought about. In this report we do not pretend to have the final answers. In the last report on regulation and market structure our studies lead us to somewhat definitive conclusions. In this report besides certain definitive conclusions and suggestions, we have also raised basic issues, questioned fundamental assumptions that are often made in discussions of governance and its role in development. We hope to highlight interesting and thus far underplayed aspects of law, policy, administration, structure of organizations and institutional arrangements. The overarching design of political institutions can constrain regulatory organizations. Political economy naturally cannot but be a part of the discussions. For the specific and contextual understanding which would lead to recommendations for improvement, sectoral and specialist knowledge is also necessary. As such the papers cover a wide range from the social and political situation, to sector specific descriptions, to institutions in general. The focus in most papers is on the constraints that stand in the way of the development of infrastructure in the country, and on how they can be overcome. As such, despite the detours into theory and concepts and case facts, the purpose is pragmatic. In some very basic problems we do not have ready solutions but nevertheless since they are very important we have discussed them. One such problem is of deprivation and extreme inequality in the country, correction of which is a larger problem. GOOD GOVERNANCE IN AN INEQUITIOUS SOCIETY The limitation of the very notion of good governance in societies with extreme inequalities and severe deprivation is a theme that runs through Chapter 2 and is also picked up again by Keshab Das in the discussion of the problems with rural infrastructure (Section 7.1). It is also covered by D’Mello in the discussion on why social impact and environmental impact analysis thus far have been farcical. Similarly, in the story of the brutal evictions of industrial workers and slum dwellers from Delhi (Delhi Janwadi Adhikar Manch, Section 5.2), the facts of repression and denial of living spaces are brought out without much comment. The authors’ pessimism in these cases is not difficult to understand. They justifiably take the position that it is capitalist development which is at the root of this oppressive behaviour of the state, and the experience in India as also possibly in many other countries, including in England during its industrialization, are testimony enough. Nevertheless late industrializing East Asia has been able to avoid such exclusion through the egalitarian income distribution that they started with, thanks to their land reforms. So it is not growth per se through the market, but the fact that we have started out on the wrong foot in not ensuring basic endowments to all, that is the source of the problem. We underscore this theme in Chapter 2. The pathos of the poor in India is not the suffering per se but its futility. If through that suffering a capital strong enough to unambiguously carry through the industrial transformation could have been assured then that suffering, however unfair would not have been in vain, since at least future generations would have gained. So today praxis, whether arising out of guilt, or hope and confidence, demands the assurance of endowments to those without it, to bring them into the market. Without that all infrastructural effort including those directly targeted at the poor and otherwise neglected villages would come to naught. Das (in Section 7.2) brings out the fate of the much touted rural infrastructure project of the Gujarat government, the eventual failure of which could have been anticipated given a reasonable familiarity of such target-oriented schemes, and the rural situation. DISPLACEMENT, RESETTLEMENT, REHABILITATION, AND THE LAND CONSTRAINT It is a moot point that today the concern for displacement and the poor arise because of the risks they impose upon 4 India Infrastructure Report 2002 infrastructure projects, the so called land acquisition and environmental risks. Even then it is good that the matter has come out into the open. Private and accountable financial institutions like Development Finance Institutions (DFIs) rather than governments and their parastatals, have brought these issues to the fore, even if for their own enlightened self interest. So justice may still be possible, if only to expand the railways and provide better roads. The way ahead as we had brought out in IIR 2001 was in replacing the existing colonial land acquisition act with one that defines the public purpose, and creates the space for negotiated settlement, and involves the displaced in the projects. In the cities it lies in less of master plans and more of land markets, less planning and more adherence to basic rules relating to land use. Nothing could help slum dwellers and others facing eviction better than higher floor space indices (FSIs). Elitist abhorrence of concrete jungles apart, it is the growing and densely built up cities that cheapen and make feasible the task of infrastructural coverage for the majority of the population. These are ideas that need to be brought out with greater force and discussed, hopefully, in a future issue of the IIR. In the present report the solution to the problem of urban land for the poor has been only sketchily discussed. Transfer of development rights (TDRs) (see Kothari, Section 8.2) which allows public services to come up quickly is one important possibility in large cities with considerable difficulties in acquiring land due to both valuation asymmetry and contingent titles—illegal squatters, slums etc. The appreciation that results through TDRs (the social or external gain) is rendered internal through the allowed higher densities in the transfer location. In growing cities subject to severe distortions, and unscientific land use, TDRs can help to correct these distortions. A less general but eminently practical solution to some of the slums that stand in the way of vital infrastructural development is provided by the story of Mumbai’s railway slums, covered by Nandini and Prem Kalra (Section 5.3). The essential value of the approach lies in giving up the pretence of the legal title and recognizing the de facto rights of slum dwellers to some urban space. With that approach the railway slums could in fact be removed or circumscribed in a manner that allowed railway operations to be conducted smoothly and to even expand, for the benefit of all. It is this exploration and pursuit of win-win solutions that is the key to all problems of social existence. There are of course better and more global solutions which can come through development that is labour absorbing at the same time. Slum clearance when combined with TDRs can be a potent force if there is clarity on the objective and functions of a city and the elitist hijack of land use as in Delhi is avoided. Delhi’s land has been preferentially allotted to institutions, defence personnel, and upper middle classes with very little or none of the land being earmarked for the working class. This exclusion by design would most certainly make land beyond the reach of all but the very wealthy and corrupt. Absurdly small floor space indices have brought about a virtual vacuum in the middle. A strange, monstrous and other-worldly city with the president having an airfield in front of his residence and most of the powerful having acres of garden space around their spread out bungalows, hogging vital central space, has grown. The rest of the people have to spend vast amounts of fuel, time and effort criss-crossing this centre of gardens and palaces every day. It is important for radical scholars to understand that monstrosities such as Delhi or Bombay are not a necessary creation of capitalist development. Successful transformations in the West and elsewhere in East Asia have created London, Philadelphia, New York and what is of greater relevance to us Shanghai, Seoul and Kuala Lumpur with spaces for all, unconstrained by elitist architectural considerations and monopolization of central places. Similar dysfunctional cities though none on the scale of Delhi are to be found in societies that have not successfully carried out the industrial transformation— much of Latin America, Mexico and the Philippines. Extreme inequality in these societies creates spaces for vast informal sector and so slums as also for palaces in city centres. When the exclusivity inherited from colonial rulers in the administration of the country is additionally located in such cities a Delhi results. Had Islamabad been created in Rawalpindi, a Delhi would have resulted. In Section 5.4, Rath and Ramakrishnan bring out their vast experience with resettlement and rehabilitation (R&R) with power and other large projects. The National Thermal Power Corporation’s (NTPC) record of R&R is far better than that of government parastatals because of a certain degree of professionalism, a seriousness with regard to the laws of the land, and an ability to afford the costs of R&R. Much more though is desired especially with regard to the management of ash pits. Recently as activism among those affected has increased and the expectations of the displaced have gone up, the attempt has been to minimize displacement. This has large negative consequences. The lands acquired are such as to leave large pockets of people without a sufficient buffer between them and the project. Negative externalities have therefore to be borne by those who are technically not displaced but who hardly have the resources to mitigate the ill effects of these externalities. This is the most abhorrent development and needs to be corrected. In our discussion of a possible approach to land acquisition in IIR 2001, I had argued that in land acquisition there is a case for collective decision making—an all or none approach with uniform base prices for all—since partial Overview 5 acquisition for carrying out activities incompatible with the prior activities in the area would impose heavy burden on those whose lands are not acquired. Also such a process would avoid the manipulation of the average price of acquisition. Very importantly Rath and Ramakrishnan stress the need for professional bodies, perhaps organized as non-profit organizations that can carry out R&R on behalf of companies and enterprises investing in infrastructure. In unbundling project related activities to professionalize a distinctly different activity from the rest of the project the scope for specialization and skill development is large. R&R is far too technical to be left entirely to local non-governmental organizations (NGOs). And is too different from the activities of managers who are used to dealing with people in organizations and consumers, not groups, organized or otherwise. Moreover, the project affected people are from a strata of society about whom they have little experience. Such arrangements would not let the experience that worthy productive enterprises like the NTPC and others have in R&R activities to go waste. The experience could then be more widely available. So should not NGOs, FIs, and companies like the NTPC come together to set up specialist R&R organizations? They also highlight the need for project affected people to be involved in their own R&R especially in house construction. The ritualization of the environment and social impact analysis that goes on is the theme of D’Mello’s paper (Section 5.7). He goes on to argue why an environment impact assessment (EIA) and social impact assessment (SIA) need to go together. More substantially in a labour surplus economy it would be wrong to assume that those displaced with money compensation for their lands would be able to restore their livelihoods. The actual practice of R&R today is ‘antithetical to the values of a liberal and plural society’. The fact that infrastructural projects, especially dams, have attracted many public interest litigations (PILs) imply that those affected and displaced are not being treated fairly. A good E/SIA would according to the author have to necessarily recognize the existence of different classes since they are vulnerable in varying degrees. Typically poor peasants, tribals and agricultural workers (unless they are able to migrate to the irrigated areas) generally suffer most. An aseptic cost– benefit analysis would not do. Given the current modes of R&R, and the framework for land acquisition, PILs and the courts have been the only solace for those affected by large projects like the Narmada. Struggle was important in being able to get the settlement, but the tide has turned. Courts have turned away from judicial activism in the interest of the poor. But courts cannot be expected to reflect much more than the class orientation of the state of which they are a part. Thus the judicial activism of the eighties and early nineties has given way to rulings that have upheld executive actions even when they have hurt the poor as in the Delhi pollution-related evictions (Section 5.2). Reacting to strong pressure from the environment groups and with a concern for mounting levels of air pollution in Delhi the closure of industries has hurt workers and the poor. Pushed out from their original jhuggi–jhopris they have no work in their new locales where they are forced to resettle. THE CONSTITUTIONAL AND LEGAL FRAMEWORK We have a parliamentary democracy in which the separation of the roles of the executive and the legislature is not as clear cut as in the presidential form in the US. Anant and Jaivir Singh (Section 4.1) discuss the implications of the overarching constitutional framework for regulation and governance in the context of commercialization of infrastructure. Transparency of the regulator is particularly challenging since unlike in the US, the separation of powers between the executive and the legislature is not complete and not subject to the concurrence of the judiciary in the regular course. This carries over into the functioning of the regulator. This means that regulators, to be effective, have the onus of promoting voice and equity decisions. This means that right structuring of the regulatory authority, and appointment of the regulator are crucial tasks. If errors are made therein, the consequences are likely to be severe. This explains well the experience of regulation in the financial, electricity and telecom sectors. The last case is discussed in the paper. The government’s and the TRAI’s (Telecom Regulatory Authority of India) powers are obfuscated in the act itself. Moreover it has now become standard practice ‘to construct [regulatory] institutions to include a wing that acts as a court’. While this general trend has come about because ‘civil courts are overwhelmingly clogged that it is felt that special/tribunals will speed up justice …This fragmentation of the court system might speed up cases but surely lead to inefficiencies that are generated by ambiguous jurisdiction. The key problem with such fragmentation is that it inhibits the development of a unified legal system [in this case] in an important area of contract law.’ The notions of public hearings and consultative papers that the regulators go through do not in themselves amount to giving voice or equity. There is nothing in the law that makes regulators decide in favour of consumers or the people. Most of the reform acts or the specific acts that have created regulators do not start with the consumer interest. Neither are the advisory, overseeing bodies specified under the law representative of the consumer interest. Thus Ajay Pandey’s study of the case of the first power tariff norms fixation by the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission (CERC) (Section 9.1) shows that despite the consultation 6 India Infrastructure Report 2002 studies, reports of the consultants, and the motion of inviting the public to participate, the decisions as such were circumscribed by its own limited understanding of the issues. We cannot exclude the possibility that it may have been influenced only by those who made themselves heard. All parties involved were not equally vociferous and the CERC did little to have the voice of the SEBs brought into the discussions. Similarly, the Draft Bill 2001 which lays down the membership of the selection committee that would appoint the State Electricity Regulatory Commission (SERC)/CERC members and chairpersons, indicates that they are all officials of the government. This in itself is not the problem, but the law allows the choice of the commission to be a legal person—a retired judge, in which case the conditions pertaining to skills and experience can be overruled by the government. The danger of regulatory capture is also highlighted by the Prayas Group (Section 6.7). Anant and Singh also see much harm in judicial activism however well intentioned the motives, since the judiciary is best at hearing out competing claims to make a ruling, not prima facie making a choice. Such activism is also violative of the doctrine of separation of powers and as such long term degradation of the institutions of governance is likely, if such trends continue. Anant and Singh in Section 4.1 discuss the functionality of instruments of regulation especially for the control and management of externalities. The choice between liability rules and property rights would have to be made not arbitrarily, but based on the nature of the damage or effects that the externality in question can bring. When these are not predicted then property rules or rights work better. Thus, ‘The advantage of the liability rule is clearly related to the ability to correctly assess average harm. If the system (legal, administrative and procedural) systematically underestimates harm then the liability principle can do much worse than the property rule. If the problem at hand is such that it involves idiosyncratic valuation of the resource in question where the two parties have different private valuations then property rules dominate over liability rules. Under a property rule, transfers take place only if the valuation of the owner is less than the valuation of potential takers, and that too through a compensation acceptable to the owner. If liability rules were used in such instances with compensation being based on averages of values, more than optimal level of takings or dispossession will take place.’ Joshi and Anuradha (Section 4.3) bring out the features of an ideal framework for a law relating to commercialization of infrastructure, and posit the existing legal framework in several sectors, to point out their limitations and constraints in bringing about private participation and ownership. Even without laws through an executive order private sector can be brought in, but the risks would tend to be high in such cases, because executive decisions and policies can be reversed. Some of the important lacunae in the existing laws are that the law: • may not allow for private interest to be created; • may have only inadequate protection of private investment; • may not vest all relevant rights required for the development of the facility; • may not provide for due recognition and enforcement of lenders’ rights; • may not have provision for the imposition of tariff/ fee/toll; • may not provide for an adequate independent regulatory mechanism; • may not provide for adequate dispute settlement mechanism. As several states go past BOT (build, operate and transfer) laws for private sector participation, some of these but not all are getting rectified. ACCESS TO INFORMATION Abha Singhal Joshi (Section 4.4) building on her report in IIR 2001 on the freedom of information bill, makes a comprehensive assessment of the same, concluding that the bill does not go very far in ensuring that people will have the right to information. Too many exclusions, many of them of the blanket type, too many situations where public interest can be used to deny information and the noninclusion of private companies with a large public aspect, have all marred the bill. They would mean that while we would have a law in form, in spirit it would hardly provide for information the way the right to information provides in the US and in a few other progressive countries. The processes gone through by the Shourie Committee were not laudable enough. Few people outside the bureaucracy and the government were contacted before the draft was drawn up. Many of the criticisms made against the draft do not find recognition. The right to information is all the more vital in India where, the law that has created regulators does not give adequate independence to the regulator, and also, there are no directions on the regulator specifying his principal task to lie in ensuring the consumer interest. With much privatization of infrastructure envisaged, disclosure to users and citizens and to those being displaced, could have been explicitly brought under the ambit of the law. What is most strange is that there is no effective remedy in the proposed law when the government denies a particular information. All that the citizen can do is to appeal to the designated officer within the government. Citizens’ monitoring of infrastructure services, and more generally of government functioning, is one way of putting Overview 7 pressure on public bodies and civil servants to improve performance and bring about accountability. The idea could indeed be extended to monitoring and participation (even in the design of various activities and facilities). One may well ask why the media cannot carry out this function. Media can be very useful in drawing attention and concern. Its power therein is unchallenged but media has its own constraints of what is news or worthwhile to report. The Public Affairs Committee (PAC)—a Bangalore based civil society organization reports (Paul and Gopakumar, Section 4.2) its pioneering experience in monitoring of public services and more generally of providing feed back to local bodies and others that have the responsibility of providing these services. The success of their efforts whenever there has been some interest on the part of the local bodies to improve is indicative of the potential in the approach. Key to the success is the objective assessment through reliable and validated schedules. This objectification even if not entirely justifiable is very important since it provides a yardstick to measure the local bodies’ performance, and we know from motivation theory that performance measurement on a regular and objective basis can be a powerful motivator. From the point of view of the citizen the institutionalization of the feed back, and monitoring that the approach provides, overcomes the free rider problem that is always there in any such collective effort. And this is what makes the money spent on building organizations like the PAC worthwhile. In a very active democracy that has taken root very early in our development these initiatives point to the right direction for action. Manikutty (Section 4.5) finds that active promotion and creation of an institutional mechanism for community participation can greatly improve the efficacy and efficiency of public services. The case studied is of drinking water in two different locales, one with and another without community participation (CP). Not only the additional local knowledge that CP brings in at the design stage but also the sense of ownership and commitment that it brings about are important. Cost and effort can come down dramatically if monitoring of the service quality and levels is done by the potential beneficiaries. They have a natural incentive to correct failures once an institutional/ organizational framework that involves them is in place. ENVIRONMENTAL POLLUTION In IIR 2001 we had briefly touched upon the problem of environmental pollution bringing out the dimensions of failure in this aspect. India probably has one of the poorest records on control of environmental pollution. We had then suggested that in having bitten more than they could chew, the pollution control boards of most states have more or less failed completely. Very ambitious laws exist merely on paper and even when there is some monitoring the punishments have been too little. Recent court based closures of polluting units have only compounded the problem since they do not recognize the costs and benefits of mitigation and ignore far better and appropriate approaches to the problem. We had also suggested that some states like Gujarat in widely dispersing polluting industries ostensibly for backward area development have maximized their negative externalities. In this report we have taken the matter further. Atiyah Curmally (Section 5.1) reviews the literature on approaches to the control of pollution and makes that wide-ranging and most relevant literature accessible to the policy maker. In worrying about the choice of instruments like permits (tradable or otherwise) and in general property rules, fines, and liability rules under various situations and in contextualizing them to the situation current in India, she is able to lead to the understanding that there is much that the state can do to reduce the effects of environmental pollution. I have elsewhere argued that historically after a certain stage in the transformation process when incomes are high, the concern for the environment suddenly increases leading to a flurry of changes in rules and governance to result in a rather quick clean up of the environment. This has happened in Japan and Korea and will soon happen in China. Nevertheless it is possible, without much cost, even before such a stage is reached, to mitigate the worst effects of pollution if an economic and participatory approach is adopted, rather than the blanket ban or the command and control approach that is current today. The elements of these would be to prioritize and distinguish between various kinds of pollution and choose the instruments for tackling the same carefully. In other words to worry integrally about not only pollution but its differential effects—the costs of mitigation, monitoring and policing, the value of punitive measures and deterrent, and the appropriateness of the instrument before instituting measures. Experiences of other countries that have used some of these alternative measures are also discussed. The paper also comprehensively reviews the initiatives thus far, to provide an explanation of why these have generally failed. Waiting for growth to take care of pollution may be quite misplaced in India. Not only is the transformation of the economy not assured but even if it were to happen it would hardly be the quick process that is current in East Asia. Vast income inequalities would mean that the poor and the marginalized would bear a very large part of the pollution and environmental costs as they do today. The Delhi Janwadi Adhikar Manch (in Section 5.2 and in Box 5.1.2 of 5.1) bring out the tragic effects of pollution control on the poor in Delhi, via the usual command and control approach 8 India Infrastructure Report 2002 discussed by Curmally. The political economy of pollution and its control is today in Delhi a case of systematic assault by the state on the poor. (An equally abhorrent case is that of displacement—both in rural and urban areas which we have already mentioned). In both these situations although we do not have ready and well honed solutions we are able to say what is dramatically wrong with the current system and indicate the more workable and fair approaches possible today. CONTEXTUALIZING REGULATORY CHOICES Excessive and premature regulation, even when formal as through legally constituted and independent regulators, may itself be a cause of governance failure. Electricity, telecom, and the current proposals for water and gas have the potential of this dysfunctionality. Historically, (in the now developed economies) regulation has usually been a post development phenomenon. There is a natural contestability or functionality to the monopolist pricing that arises when the network is rapidly expanding wherein therefore only light supervision, not amounting to regulation but some intervention around standards and rules is all that is necessary. This viewpoint which goes against the current approach of bringing about complex regulatory mechanisms3 needs serious consideration. The current proposals would if pushed4 create a humunguous superstructure of regulators that would dwarf the 5000 active regulators who existed in the US prior to deregulation. Areas like gas pipelines, water, telecom and electricity in rural areas, where much network expansion can quickly take place face a real danger of getting into regulatory quagmires. The possibility of capture by the regulated to ensure high returns without efforts to overcome risk and develop the market is large. Jayanth Varma discusses this theme in Section 6.1 and then goes on to develop the insight that what is required out of private infrastructure (today) is not just private finance as such but private entrepreneurship. ‘The private sector would then bear the risks and reap the rewards of infrastructure projects. The design and location of these projects would follow economic logic [most vital for the country today], rather than the dictates of political considerations’. The gains in allocative efficiency in bringing the private sector are far larger than 3 It is interesting that in all the regulatory initiatives in India thus far, the option of an index based incentive regulation, which could have been much lighter than the current cost plus detailed regulation in electricity and telecom, has been entirely ignored. In the last IIR I had argued strongly for such mechanisms. 4 More than being pushed there would be an autonomous tendency for expansion and growth of the regulatory apparatus since there would be new space for the bureaucracy to expand. merely in project construction and management. And the private sector would enter in a big way if the rewards in entering, in bringing in technology and new modes of working, and contesting are high. (The benefits for the consumer too would be very large particularly through the expansion of the network and in the use of innovative technologies and modes of working.) This is not to deny that a ‘small number of strategic infrastructure projects may remain that the state considers important, but the private sector does not consider attractive. It is only for these few projects that the state needs to step in either by undertaking the project with public funds or by providing subsidies or credit enhancement’. Atanu Chakraborty (Section 6.2) brings out the salient features of the proposed Gujarat Gas Act. As one actively involved in its creation he is best placed to outline the pulls and pressures that worked against the Gujarat government going ahead with the act. The jurisdiction of the Gujarat (state) government to legislate on gas was contested, though the matter is rather clear. The act creates a common carrier mode for gas transport separating the trade in gas from the pipes business. It can serve as a working model for other state governments serious about gas network development. Chakraborty reports that the apprehensions that the regulator would be weak, and a state owned enterprise in gas transmission is unwarranted, are quite misplaced. ‘Removal of a member of the Commission is fairly difficult, and the Act lays out a comprehensive procedure.... Transmission being a natural monopoly had to be structured carefully and it was that consideration that led the state to set up a venture where all the stakeholders are represented. It is not the usual government company but one that has formal participation of stakeholders’. CORRUPTION AND BRIBERY Ajay Pandey (Section 6.3) reviews the economic literature on corruption to bring certain insights into the discussion on governance. Thus we learn that the welfare prompting aspect of corruption, much in vogue some time ago, arises only under special conditions and only if second order effects are ignored. It makes sense to define various types of corruption since their sources and effects could be dramatically different. Decentralization, competition among officials, supervision by key decision making authority, greater role of markets and private sector in public services go along with much less corruption than otherwise. Generally the empirical evidence supports the contention that corruption reduces growth, as revealed in cross country regression studies. Praveen Kulshreshtha (Section 6.6) presents a model of bribery where he is able to argue that previous contentions showing bribery as welfare promoting is wrong even in Overview 9 terms of the first order effects. In my own discussion of corruption in Chapter 2 (which is a more general phenomenon than bribery) I present the case of China which despite its highly corrupt society is growing most rapidly and suggest that while corruption does generate vast rents, if these are invested in productive businesses the growth impetus is large. Corruption therein is a means for the emergence of the bourgeoisie out of the party elite and hence its functionality. This situation is changing very rapidly though as corruption has now become dysfunctional, and expectedly the Chinese government is cracking down severely on it. Kulshreshtha next (Box 6.3.1) documents very briefly the World Bank’s approach to governance, important aspects of which have been capacity building for administration especially for management of public services and institutional development. Success though has been mixed because of technocratic orientation of its projects, weak contextualization, and uniform prescription of what is best practice. Moreover governance related actions do come in conflict with traditional project lending. Until recently the World Bank ignored the available options for institutional reform. Thus mechanisms of decentralization or voice and competition were overlooked by the Bank. ACCOUNTING FOR TRANSPARENCY Gujarathi and Barua (Section 6.4) look at the attempt by state and local governments (SLGs) in many countries to find the appropriate accounting and reporting of infrastructure assets. ‘In many cases, standard-setters have embraced accrual accounting for infrastructure assets as a part of the larger efforts to institute better accountability regimes and improved governance in the public sector’. But there is no magical accounting solution to the problem of reporting the worth and contribution of public infrastructure. When the accrual systems have been grafted on to public infrastructure nothing very significant is gained by investors and users as the set-ups are public, with long and extendable lives. The solution may well be increased disclosure of information that goes beyond the financial to cover physical and analytical information, demand studies, etc that may have been made. Cash flow based methods may still be all right if supplemented with adequate information. LESSONS FROM GOVERNANCE FAILURES The two most visible cases of governance failure have been in the electricity sector (with regard to the independent power project (IPP) policy and subsidization) and in the financial sector. The results have also been very severe. The failures therein would have in a major way also contributed to the recession and to the negation of the fruits of reform. They have also created an adverse climate and opinion against reform. I have come across umpteen bureaucrats arguing against any kind of reform in the electricity sector because of what happened with Enron and Orissa. Both the IPP’s policy and the reform of SEBs are primarily intellectual failures, despite the obvious governance failure and probability of high corruption in the case of Enron. These had been brought out in the IIR 2001. In this report using the Godbole Committee’s findings Subodh Wagle of the Prayas Group (Section 6.7) draws out the failures in the case of Enron and the harm it poses to consumer interest (and of course to the Maharashtra State Electricity Board (MSEB)). The kind of massive and sequential failure at many administrative and decision making levels in the Enron case can only be countered by a vigilant citizenry working hard for transparency, accountability and participation of the people. The Prayas Group’s activities, including their struggle in courts and in public hearings of the Maharashtra regulator were instrumental in bringing to the fore the sordid details of the arrangement that took the nation and the consumer for a ride. The financial sector’s story has been a string of regulatory failures of the SEBI and what is not generally appreciated of the RBI in a very crucial aspect of any modern economy viz. in the regulation of banking. The learning from past mistakes has been at best weak in these organizations. Many factors have been responsible—poor skills and ability, the lack of professionalism, and an inability and unwillingness to crucially monitor key aspects of the financial sector. Barua analyses three scams—The Securities Scam of 1992; the (Section 6.5) Madhavpura Mercantile Cooperative Bank (MMCB) Scam of 2001; and the US-64 Crisis of 2001— to argue that ‘there is an urgent need to harmonize the regulations for different segments of the financial sector to reflect the basic inter-connected nature of operations of different segments’, for possible unification of regulations, for separation of the functions of development of the sector and its regulation, and the ‘extensive use of appropriate statistical tools for data analysis to anticipate and defuse a developing crisis’ and for speedier processes for dealing with frauds. The key to achieving these is professionalization of the regulatory functions. The financial sector’s health is crucial to all other sectors including infrastructure and the sector as such has a large regulatory aspect. RURAL POVERTY, INFRASTRUCTURE, GYANDOOT AND The approach to poverty has been to mitigate the same by acts of redistribution. It is well known that all of these have had very little effect because of the vast leakages and the very high costs of their administration. The Integrated Rural 10 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Development Programme (IRDP) programmes and the various special employment programmes are of this genre. Their true role may have been little more than to create space for the expansion of the bureaucracy and counter potential dissent among the poor. Keshab Das (Section 7.1) reviews very briefly the rural growth and development experience with a focus on infrastructure arguing that privatization would not work because of the low affordability and problems of excludability specific to the rural context. While the government’s role is potentially large, state failure as exemplified by the IRDP and similar programmes would mean that status quo would not deliver either. The best way out of the mess is to bring back the agenda of land reforms since that by creating productive endowments for the poor can bring about their participation, and make them afford infrastructure. Better institutional and administrative mechanisms and governance improvements are possible for an enhanced role of the state, which is inevitable if there is willingness to seriously strive for rural infrastructure. In Section 7.2 Das takes the case of a specific infrastructural development effort—the programme of the Gokul Grams taken up with much fanfare in Gujarat. He brings out the dimensions of their failure which are more or less the same as in typical rural development programmes, despite claims to the contrary. Community participation could have helped, so would empowerment of the village and taluka panchayats which were actually responsible for the implementation of the programme. Brij Kothari, Avinash Pandey and Amita Chudgar (Section 7.3) report the strange case of electronic networking in rural Dhar, one of the most backward districts in rural Madhya Pradesh. The personal initiative, dynamism and leadership of the local collector resulted in the development of an electronic network with branches and nodes in taluka headquarters and the main servers in the district headquarters and dial up access in many villages with plans to cover most clusters of villages, so that no villager is far from these soochnalayas. This Gyandoot project is remarkable in having involved the people not merely as users but as contributors and initiators so that the sense of ownership and participation is very strong. It has a high probability of being commercially viable and self-sustaining. The content of the information made available at the soochnalayas and the interactivity that is possible for such tasks as getting copies of records, certificates, complaints, and the commitment of the local government offices to respond to queries are the beginnings of true e-governance. The ultimate potential of the computer and the internet for e-governance is immense since at current rates of penetration it is likely to cover a very large part of the population if special public arrangements like these soochnalayas can do what the subscriber trunk dialling/ public call office (STD/PCO) booths did to the use of telecom. Of course the project would hardly have been possible without the initiative of the collector. Now that one Gyandoot has come up, many more might be round the corner. THE URBAN SITUATION The urban situation with regard to infrastructure, especially in the big cities, depends crucially on policies and practices with regard to urban space, both built up and land. It also depends upon the capacity and resources of the urban local bodies and the constraints they have in investments and in bringing the private sector in. In the last IIR we covered the finances of urban local bodies bringing out their vulnerability. We thought we would be able to cover the major issue of the distortions in the market for urban land and space, but that for various reasons we could not do in this report. Bhavin Kothari (Section 8.2) as mentioned before brings out the potential of TDRs to overcome in part the worst effects of the distortions in the market for land and space, to allow at least some land to be made available for adding vitally necessary urban infrastructure. Bithin Datta (Section 8.1) brings out in crisp detail the present situation with regard to urban infrastructure and the organization responsible for the same—the Kanpur Development Authority (KDA). The beginnings of a slow change are there—projects have begun on build, finance, operate and transfer (BFOT) and BOT basis but much improvement is needed. Many problems arise with the management and maintenance of infrastructure due to problems at the planning stage itself—incorrect data and surveys that lead to wrong layout, improper master plans that do not recognize the ground reality, improper feasibility studies, over-ambitious standards of layout and space allocation. Thus plans that attempt to anticipate the needs of the future would be futile and almost impossible to realize. Poor coordination between the KDA and other bodies concerned—the Railways, the Nagar Nigam and the electricity board principally—have imposed huge delays and costs. These hopefully will soon be overcome since there is the beginning of the consciousness that these need to be overcome if progress has to be made. Projects which are abandoned after partial construction for various reasons, but continue to exist on paper (for accounting and procedural reasons), impose additional drain on the resources of the KDA. Illegal encroachments even during the construction of the project are rampant and have resulted in high costs and delays. Without the political will to remove these and prevent such encroachments a major constraint would continue to exist whatever the improvements in other aspects. The financial situation of the KDA though better than of many other similar organizations is under stress. Salaries Overview take up a large part of the expenses and today there is little contribution from user charges and taxes. The potential for improvement though is high if the willingness-to-pay surveys can be relied upon. Bringing about user charges would require legislative changes and the development of a framework to allow for tariffs and subsidies linked to tariffs and tolls for many of the urban services. Land development fees and user charges for water, certain roads and bridges like bypasses are eminently feasible. Mukesh Sharma (Section 8.3) continues the story of Kanpur bringing out the situation with regard to water supply and its pricing. Losses both technical and unaccounted are very large, the rates which are low are highly distortionary and do not promote judicious use of water. Going by the water charges as a proportion of income the poor cannot afford to pay more5. Binayak Rath (Section 8.6) brings out the problems with regard to solid waste management in Kanpur that are likely to be typical of most large cities in India. Despite many regulations and injunctions of the courts there is little adherence to norms as laid out in several policies and documents of the central government. Collection efficiencies both primary and secondary are poor, storage facilities are entirely inadequate, existing equipments including trucks are poorly utilized, the siting of landfills is quite improper and equipments are in poor shape. The Kanpur Nagar Nigam is poorly organized for the task, the elected members are indifferent to the problems, and the phenomenon of ‘badla workers’ is also noticeable. Some half hearted attempts at involving NGOs and privatization have naturally failed. The problem can be overcome if the space for the informal sector can be created and suitable NGOs can be actively brought in. URBAN WATER Nirmal Mohanty and Shreekant Gupta (Section 8.4), bring out the issues in the use of water markets for reforms in the sector. They argue that though ‘…informal water markets have been in existence for decades, formal markets with clearly assigned, private and transferable water rights are of relatively recent origin. …In many instances water trading has alleviated water shortages. International experience also shows that formal and developed water markets strengthen 5 Essentially the method is to show that water rates already take 2.2 per cent of family income, higher than in many countries where it takes between 0.9 and 1.8 per cent. This method of comparison is debatable and the opposite conclusion can actually be drawn which ties up with the willingness to pay surveys since the comparison is with the advanced countries. At high levels of income the share of necessities including water would be low given the nature of consumption baskets. To presume similar shares is to assume that consumption functions are homothetic over the items in the basket which is certainly not true [Editor]. 11 the incentives for conservation and more efficient use of water. For example, farmers have responded by switching to water-saving technologies and high-value, less water intensive crops. The Indian experience with water markets has been positive, although there have been only limited gains as markets have remained informal, localized and primitive. …The current challenge in India is therefore to establish formal water markets which will expand the scope of trading and make inter-sectoral water transfers possible. Further, since formal water markets have a legal basis, effective regulation can be designed to address the issue of ecological sustainability. These markets will be of significant relevance to the urban sector which has been suffering from acute shortages of water but has not been able to access informal markets. While it is true that in urban areas tariff rationalization and reforms at the distribution end can improve efficiency in water supply and use, nevertheless additional measures will be required in view of fast growing urban population. …In this context it is estimated that if five per cent of the water being used for irrigation is transferred to the urban sector, the latter’s water requirements can be met for the next fifty years. In Alandur on the outskirts of Chennai Muncipal Corporation, but part of Chennai’s urban agglomeration, citizens actually paid rather stiff connection charges and monthly fees for a new sewerage system. The rates that they paid were far higher than even the figures revealed by an earlier willingness-to-pay survey. Residents of nearby Chennai did not pay anything for sewerage facilities. This happened because of the persuasive and educational efforts of the Alandur Municipality. Mukesh P. Mathur (Section 8.5) brings out this interesting story. The case is of importance in the discussions of user charges and commercialization of urban infrastructure. The costs that people bear in being subject to denial are much higher than the cost of providing the service. This is especially true in the urban agglomerations of large cities not covered by muncipal facilities. The point had been discussed in IIR 2001. If the state cannot gear up to provide services, or even to create the framework (of regulation) for bringing in the private sector, then it should consider opening up such activities (without any regulation) to private parties to organize and build facilities. That would be better than continuing with the denial. DEVELOPMENTS IN THE ELECTRICITY SECTOR The high point in the electricity sector was the arrival of the official draft bill to usher in open access. The National Council of Applied Economic Research (NCAER) had been working on the Draft Bill 2000 which had gone through eight versions in the process of consultations among government and potential stakeholders. The current official 12 India Infrastructure Report 2002 bill 2001 is in many ways different. Ajay Pandey (Section 9.4) critically reviews the draft bill to point out its pluses, and bring out its inadequacies. A golden opportunity for reform of the electricity sector would again be missed. The bill does not start with consumer interest but with open access, yet it does not rule out all restrictions on interstate and interregional trade and transport of power, puts severe restrictions on the traders, and does not neatly solve the problem of cross subsidization through for instance bringing about direct subsidization. (See my discussion in Chapter 2.) While putting much responsibility on the regulatory commissions, there is lack of clarity of roles between government, the Central Electricity Authority (CEA) and the commissions. Similarly the bill loses an opportunity to have explicitly brought in incentive regulation. ‘There are provisions which preclude the possibilities for the sector such as competition in supply, development of pool or spot markets as any such move will require further legislative change, a time-consuming and costly process. The emergence of new sets of problems and issues …in the areas of regulatory coordination, conflicts between state and the regulators, transmission and distribution (T&D) losses, conflicts between state and central transmission utilities, besides the political fallout of attempted tariff rationalizations cannot be ruled out.’ The first day of 2001 started with the collapse of the Northern grid leaving the region with no electricity, from which it recovered only after several days. The CEA that enquired into the episode brought out the events and failures leading to the collapse. Taking off from that epsiode Puneet Chitkara, Rajiv Shekhar and Prem Kalra (Section 9.2) lay threadbare the nature of the failure and suggest ways to improve the physical management of the grid, the regulation and pricing of transmission for interstate movement of power. The current system of responsibility assignment and authority and of regulation is such as to create little incentives for effective management of the grid both in the normal course and in emergencies. The cost plus pricing that is current, neither provides for efficient management of costs nor does it provide for the correct siting of investments. They propose, comprehensively and in much detail, a fresh transmission pricing and regulatory mechanism, and ownership and management structure for transmission assets and operations that would overcome the problems with the current system and would also be much in line with the proposals for large scale unbundling of the electricity sector. Dynamic line rating systems, online data gathering devices and soft investments for condition monitoring with a view to anticipate likely weak points in the grid are possible. Very little investment may be required but they would become vitally necessary if the events leading to the grid failure are not to repeat. After the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission (CERC) rule on the availability-based tariff (ABT), giving its ABT order for bulk tariffs, the same was opposed on jurisdictional grounds by those central power corporations (CPCs) who were badly affected by the order. Ajay Pandey (Section 9.4) comprehensively reviews this order going into both the processes followed by the CERC and the rationale of the outcome. His findings are not particularly encouraging. The process followed by CERC was very open. ‘It also took expert opinion wherever required as is evident from the appointment of consultants and committees.’ But those affected by the order of CPCs took a ‘confrontational posture…More surprising however, in the process of review was the low level of involvement... of the beneficiaries’. The CERC despite apparently noting the merit of certain recommendations of the consultants with regard to consistency with the IPP policy chose to ignore the same! Similarly despite its attention being brought to significant anomalies in the definition of the rate base, the treatment of depreciation, the allowed return, the treatment of liabilities denominated in foreign currency, the CERC chose to ignore these. And the anomalies have continued to harm the sector. ‘In the end, the order despite openness in the process, looks more like a balancing act, and we will have to wait at least untils the next tariff review for a sound framework for bulk power tariff regulations to emerge’. Professionalization of the CERC is thus still awaited. Sidharth Sinha (Section 9.3) brings out the reasons for the failure of the much-touted Orissa model. He shows how the inability to measure T&D losses and the inability to achieve the desired reduction in the same resulted in the failure of the Orissa Model. Ramamohan Rao, Puneet Chitkara, and Kaushal Saxena (Section 9.5) ask, from the vantage point of the Mukta Panna Oilfield Contract with a private group, if there has not been a policy/governance failure. It does not make sense to bring in a multinational corporation (MNC) to work a proven gas/oil field where there are few risks commensurate with the large returns it would make. Liberalization of the oil sector has to be carefully worked out. TRANSPORT G. Raghuram (Section 10.1) brings out several cases of commercialization activities in the railways that have had moderate success. The incentive incompatibilities, ignorance of network effects as in the case of the Konkan Railway, the tendency to tie its partner or client into one sided contracts that the railways seem to have a propensity for come out in these cases. The success factors and the problem areas are identified and as the railways prepare themselves for large scale commercial orientation the lessons from their earlier Overview experiences would prove invaluable. Raghuram identifies eight dimensions that are crucial to the success of commercialization and rate the cases on these. The case of commercialization of catering services presents the disturbing picture of large underreporting of the sales of the railways official contract caterers. While the percentage share that the railways take from the revenues of the contractors has been significantly increased, at the same time it is difficult to monitor and measure the base. Is there an impending governance failure? Subir Gokarn (Section 10.2) reviews the liberalization in the air-transport sector and the developments therein. Significant has been the entry of the private sector in a major way into scheduled airlines that has made the domestic airline sector show the beginnings of competition. The regulatory supervisory mechanisms need to develop in the direction of independence from the government. The policy on airport infrastructure is not adequate to lead to quick development of the sector. S. Sriraman (Section 10.3) brings out the recent experiences of the state road transport undertakings. Load factors have been falling because of recently allowed private operators who have been operating on high density routes, leaving the low density and expensive routes to the State Road Transport Undertakings (SRTUs). This partial liberalization has therefore not been conducive to SRTUs restructuring for better effectiveness. Fare structures do not take into account demand factors and are not flexible enough. SRTUs need greater autonomy in this directon and routes and route bundling would have to be fairly allocated if the playing field has to be level between the SRTUs and private operators. Performance of SRTUs vary a great deal, and there are many SRTUs especially in the south whose physical parameters show the same or better efficiency than private operators. But their higher cost, especially of manpower, would nevertheless make their costs of service higher. Biju Varkkey and G. Raghuram (Section 10.4) do a detailed case study of the new Cochin International Airport that was the first airport to be built on a BOT basis. In many ways a private effort, it has nevertheless a dominant stakeholding by the Kerala government. The large traffic from the state to the Gulf, the limitations in expanding the existing airport, the enthusiastic response of people from the Gulf and the active interest of the district collector were factors that led to the start of the project. Land acquisition was difficult but was carried out despite all the hurdles. Issues of adequate and fair compensation remain. The project did not do as well as was anticipated because inter alia the assumed transfer of bilateral landings from Mumbai did not take place. The case brings out the issues in viability of airports, rehabilitation and resettlement, and in structuring 13 of projects, and draws lessons for the practice of private– public partnership. TECHNOLOGY MOVES AS CONSUMERS WAIT WLL (TELECOM SECTOR) FOR After the draft convergence bill at the end of the previous year much was expected this year in the telecom sector. Especially that it would lead to uniform licences across various segments of the telecom industry. As mentioned before instead there came WLL with limited mobility (LM) in which the consumer interest has perhaps been all but forgotten. Rekha Jain and Dheeraj Sanghi (Section 11.1) review the WLL(LM) episode bringing out the content and processes in the decision making. We realize that the only way the issues could have been resolved would have been through equivalent licences and making the terms of the cellular and fixed line operators similar, since the strong force of technological change does not allow much else. The need for ‘the clear separation of roles of the Group on Telecom and Information Technology (GOT-IT), Department of Telecom (DoT), and TRAI is underlined’. The TRAI should have a bigger role in detailing an expected development. Thus once the idea of WLL is accepted the TRAI rather than the government is best placed to work out the details. The regulatory and governance environment should have been strong enough to have left the technology use to the industry without at the same time bringing about the costs of multiple and competitng standards or technology on the consumer. The use of the ‘short distance charging area as a unit for mobility, and also for defining the rollout plans is arbitrary, and needs to go to be replaced by more naturally defined units such as districts, or defined distance’. Perhaps the biggest let down was the opportunity to separate the spectrum licences from the service licences that WLL would have offerred to the regulator. As a late comer in network expansion, increased telecom density is likely to result from a much larger and quicker penetration of cellular rather than land lines. This can be inferred from the experience of China and others in East Asia who are ahead of us in telecom development. Thus to see cellular as a value added service and only fixed line as basic is wrong. Cellular, WLL with land lines, and land lines should have been allowed same conditions of entry. The opportunity to do this was missed. Integral to efficient roll-out is the correct pricing of spectrum and making as much of it available as possible. It is perhaps socially optimal, today, for the industry and telecom users (existing and potential) to pay the costs of the defence establishment to be able to convert their equipments, so that they are able to release some more spectrum. Price 14 India Infrastructure Report 2002 of the ultimate service is important because there is both a significant and large income elasticity as well as large price elasticity. This is obvious today as cellular networks in lowering prices have witnessed jumps in their subscriber base. More importantly the spectrum should have been nearly uniformally priced across its various possible uses, bringing in a greater determinancy to the market. This is the theme of Sidharth Sinha’s (Section 11.2) discussions. He brings out the institutional structure for spectrum management, the need for more efficient use and greater availability of the spectrum, and the issues involved in auctioning of spectrum rather than licences, and the whole question of the bandwidth sizes in which unit lots of the spectrum is allocated. Dheeraj Sanghi (Section 11.3) looks at internet telephony and argues why the feature of packet-switching and hence efficient use of line capacity is not what makes internet telephony cheaper. It is the significantly higher regulated prices on long distance telephony that makes conventional telephony expensive. With the removal of these differences circuit switched telephony should be able to compete with internet telephony (which is difficult to regulate) to give rise to a new equilibrium where the former would have a distinct and large space. ‘It is high time the ban on Internet telephony is removed. It is hardly a threat to long distance telephony in the near future. And we need to reduce the cost of long distance rather than shield it from competition. When Internet telephony becomes a real competition to long distance telephony, then the TRAI may worry about the level-playing field’. With the auction of the fourth cellular licences the mergers and acquisitions (M&A) in the telecom sector are expected to speed up as the logic of scale and scope unfolds itself. In Chandlerian terms those who make the investments and moves to park themselves in a commanding position would be survivors. In the long run it is unlikely that more than a handful of firms would remain, perhaps even fewer. Today contiguity drives the deals as weaker players sell off, and others with greater value for the circle lap up such licences. M&A got a boost with the government allowing equity changes from the original license. Lokesh Garg and Venu Madhav (Section 11.5) study the M&A activities in the sector providing a rationale for the same and making an attempt to peer into the immediate future using the logic of contiguity. As that logic becomes redundant once players reach an all India presence, convergence could drive the M&A. India started with many more licences than most countries so that many more M&A would take place. ‘VOICE’ GOVERNANCE AND NETWORKING The Gyandoot project’s success with very little use of resources should alert us to the vast possibility of e-governance as a meaningful free of change in the relationship of people with the government and the provider of public services. Citizens’ feed back through the experiments and methods developed by the Samuel Paul and his group at the Public Affairs Centre Bangalore, highlights the potential value that is there in bringing the public user in regular and formal contact with the provider of the service at low cost in terms of time and effort or both. The gains in combining networking and an electronic base for such feed back on a regular (and formal) basis can be enormous. This is especially so because the usual market with either price changes or quantity changes to signal performance to the producer is not there in so many public services. Can IT potentially, with sound methodological innovations in surveying and sampling, make a difference here? Remember that the developments in real time measurement at low cost brought about unbundling and hence competition in electricity and telecom sectors. Rekha Jain and Raghuram (Section 11.4) look at the many state wide area networks (SWANS) wherein several state governments have or plan to spend to develop these networks to enable rapid and enhanced intra government communication. If indeed communication over the network comes to be recognized as valid within govenment, the gains from the resulting quicker decision making would be large. The quality too could potentially improve as much more information, and in formats far more convenient, could be made available. This is particularly important in government and public bodies where decision making has to be consistent and according to rules. As governments put out a vast array of documents and forms outlining their processes, policies and rules, the electronic media, particularly the internet, already plays a role in their dissemination. The potential to carry this further by linking a Gyandoot with the SWANs is enormous. As Jain and Raghuram bring out, the SWANs would have to put much more effort into application development conceptualizing client (both government and citizen) needs. A need driven flurry of activity to develop the software and the applications that can then go over the physical network ought to start soon. Otherwise there is a real danger that the SWANS may be limited to voice and video communication within government. Even that in itself would still be beneficial. Such is the potential of the new technology. The Challenge to Governance in India 2 15 THE CHALLENGE TO GOVERNANCE IN INDIA Sebastian Morris The tendency to ascribe failure of development policy to bad or inadequate governance has become nearly universal. It seems development finance institutions (DFIs), multilateral agencies (MLAs) like the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank, and policy-makers have all come to the conclusion that poor governance, like a multiplicative factor, reduces even the best policy and prescription to naught. One can dispute this contention in many ways. Since all acts of omission and commission, poor design of institutions and their improper working can be considered as governance failure, the contention is neither an explanation of development failure in a causal sense nor particularly useful from the point of bringing about change in economic performance (or even of governance). The notion of governance failure has to be narrowed down and carefully understood. As a truism it has the danger of masking our inadequate understanding of societies and economies or even our unwillingness to understand the specific features of particular societies. Talking about poor governance, without worrying deeply about the conditions that engender the same, may also hide an unwillingness to examine the policies and development approaches critically. In this paper we finally come to the conclusion that the leverage point for correcting governance failure lies in policy and politics; in a more restricted sense of being able to set up the correct institutional arrangements, rules and incentives for economic behaviour. Actions focussed on governance have a special autonomy and a more limited role. This paper attempts to delineate that role today in India. In the introduction we raise the conceptual and historical difficulties with the notion that sees governance failure as the cause of poor economic performance. Next we discuss why good governance needs to be distinguished from functional governance which aids and abets industrialization. That helps us to understand certain historical regularities in governance. Next we go on to discuss the interlikages between institutions, economic development and governance in India, and why internal attempts at reform thus far have failed. Finally we bring out the current failures in governance that are actionable and suggest that they are largely corrected by changes in economic policy and some intitutional initiatives. Attention to governance as such is warranted only to build organizations and initiatives for commercialization and privatization, and for appropriate changes in the law and in the development of frameworks for regulation and contracting out. Governance—Cause or Effect Governance through the entire system (of government and its parastatals) is more often not the leverage point for change, but has to be effected by simultaneous changes in other dimensions of society—economic policy, politics, and law. The contrary position is not very useful, since it immediately, raises the question: how does one bring about better governance other than by appeal to political will, a much abused term? It is important and of utmost relevance that the nineteenth century, despite absence of MLAs and DFIs saw more countries industrially transforming1, than the twentieth. 1 Industrial transformation, is the second major social revolution after man emerged, and without it no society (other than through rents and transfers) can aspire towards high and increasing incomes. There is nothing like sidestepping industrialization for a society of any decent size, despite the opportunity to leap frog and avoid particular industries that the emergence of the services sector as one in its own right brings about. 16 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Indeed the only successful independent transformations that can be said to have begun unambiguously in the twentieth century are those of the East Asian tigers (South Korea, Taiwan, China, Vietnam, Thailand and possibly Malaysia) where the role of MLAs was marginal at best. The Soviet industrialization which was successful had collapsed, and is in the process of acquiring a more sustainable capitalist character. These facts should open the minds of policy-makers to the possibility that DFIs and MLAs may have been quite wrong in their policy approach to development. Certainly, the hope that with actions at the international level development can be engineered faster than otherwise has been dashed. Otherwise the twentieth century should have seen nearly all countries (except perhaps the African) to being well on their way to industrial transformation. It is important to note that good governance as conventionally understood—fair, transparent and accountable—was not a necessary characteristic of successful countries at every point in their history. Corrupt Societies have also Transformed The US in the 1920s or earlier was a very corrupt society. So is China today. Despite that it grows very fast. So have many other societies been during some part of their history.2 Corruption in societies does present a pattern of sorts. With a critical level of development it seems to fall, sometimes very dramatically. Corruption came down rather suddenly in the US after the 1920s. The jailing of Al Capone in 1932 may have been the turning point in the US towards a relatively corruption-free society. Today China is dealing with corruption with a firm hand.3 Taiwan and Korea today value honesty in public life far more than they did in their recent past. The early years of industrialization do seem to be more corruption ridden and prone to governance failures than the post-transformation phase. So, is the importance of governance, and its dysfunctionality an aspect of the phase of development? And so negating a priori any universally valid relationship between good governance and development? See Box 2.1. Another Word for State Failure? The Gerschenkron notion that the later a country industrializes the greater has been the role of the state 2 We know that industrialization is a messy process and good governance, as we understand it today was neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition. Indeed the early period of industrial transformation has typically been one of contests and class struggles wherein ‘rent’ or plunder were barely distinguishable from capital. 3 Over a few thousand corrupt officials and people have been jailed or sentenced to death during the last few years in China, on charges of corruption. See Box 2.2 on Corruption in China. See also Zhao Dengju (2000). (Gerschenkron, 1966) is again a historical regularity that has held true to date. So far there has not been a single violation of this regularity. Therefore is the insistence on good governance as a pre-condition to the efficacy of development policy a round about (and confusing) way of admitting the Gerschenkron theses by mainstream economists? When the insistence on governance is so intense as it is today, then the state4 ought to be at the centre stage. The debate on state and market failure has led to deep insights into the factors of success in East Asia and failure elsewhere. State failure has been cogently developed in the literature wherein the class base of the society, particular orientation of the bureaucracy, and the policies pursued, and the appropriateness of economic instruments of control have been related to present cogent stories. We draw much from this literature. Prosperity Inequality, and Governance Today, the causation is assumed to be from governance to development. It may, and often does run the other way too, as numerous examples from history will show. As mentioned earlier, China after going through a phase of high corruption and poor (but nevertheless functional) governance is now cracking down on corruption. Is it that with ‘middle incomes’ the value of good governance has gone up? And hence its pursuit? Similarly, was the sudden change away from corruption in the US during the 1920s the result of economic compulsions arising out of the high and widespread growth of the roaring twenties? As incomes rise for all with the industrial transformation, and when the majority of the people cross a certain level of income (and are satiated in a basic sense), their ability to be concerned about immediate non-economic aspects of life—relationships, orderliness, access to public facilities and fairness, improves. Whereas below this level, the struggle is for survival. With a decent living people’s ability to resist the unfairness and waste in public bodies improve. In China and South Korea with very little inequality of incomes such a phase has come very suddenly. In South Asia and Latin America with pronounced income inequalities even when the rich are well beyond that threshold level of income most others are not, so a sudden change is not discernable. Visible poverty coexists with affluence. Ghettos, a vast service sector, urban sprawls and slums along with isolated and protected private clean spaces result. Good governance in such situations of extreme deprivation may then merely imply that state and public institutions are only responsible to the rich and the upper classes and so may be highly oppressive on the poor who 4 Even corporate governance is determined through frameworks, policies and actions of the state. The Challenge to Governance in India 17 Box 2.1 States, Governance, and Industrialization: A Historical Review STATE, CLASS AND GOVERNANCE States have an existence apart from that of governments and their role is best conceptualized as the management of the economy and society within the constraints imposed by the coalition of classes that constitute society. The state and institutions in England during the industrial revolution, if one goes by the stories of the poor houses, the poor laws, the treatment of children and petty criminals, were hardly fair or moral, even by the standards of the society then. But they were functional (or at least not dysfunctional) in the sense of not having stood in the way of the first transformation- that forever changed society.1 Hence states and institutions may be distinguished on the lines of whether or not they aided the process of transformation of society into an industrial society. Thus we distinguish between a governance that is functional in the sense of aiding and abetting the industrial transformation; and dysfunctional governance in that the state in their behaviour, rules and institutions delayed or indefinitely postponed the industrialization. Rather than economic performance per se, it is useful to think of industrial transformation as the goal of all non-industrial societies. THE WESTERN INDUSTRIALIZATIONS The late eighteenth century state in France and its institutions were rendered dysfunctional with the beginnings of capitalism in France and gave way in the French Revolution to make possible the development of bourgeois society. While the unfairness of that pre-revolutionary state and society is quite obvious, that was not its weakness. The basis of the state which lay in the dysfunctional class (the aristocracy and the landed gentry), and its feudal form were barriers to change. These therefore were violently displaced by a revolution for a new society to emerge. But unlike in England where an unchallenged bourgeoisie reigned, the French had to create or at least strengthen a vastly weaker bourgeoisie. It was only with the modernization of Napoleon Bonaparte that bourgeois development (industrialization via capitalist development) could be put on an irreversible if slow footing. The travails of the second Napoleon show that the state had to play a new role—that of balancing the interests of not only the various sections of the bourgeoisie but also between classes. This was so because in France, the rising bourgeoisie had to share the space of the state with an upper section of the working class, rich farmers, remnants of the old ruling class and a vast bureaucracy. The coalition state in France unlike in Germany a little later under Bismarck, was only able to bring about a much slower transformation of the economy than in Germany. In Germany industrialization began in earnest when its elite landed interests—the Junkers—turned themselves into capitalists. With a state that had its power base in merchants and landlord-turned-capitalists, its tasks were not as deeply contested, as in France. Germany therefore transformed very quickly. In America, without the baggage of a feudalism, the beginnings of industrialization required, as a first condition, the overthrow of the British to form a large market for the benefit of American industry. The simple mechanisms of common tariffs and public investments in areas of market failure—standards, technical education, support for local production of arms and ammunition were used. But it is only with the victory of the North in the Civil War that bourgeois development could be said to have reached a point of irreversibility. One of the important issues in the Civil War was slavery which was declared illegal. But it was the right of the Union to have a common tariff to which the Southern agrarian interests were opposed, that was the real underlying issue. For the North however it was important that the American home market for their manufacturers remain one. The freedom of slaves as the visible issue allowed the North to seize the moral high ground and strike at the South. THE DYSFUNCTIONAL STATE IN BRAZIL Governance in a narrow or moral sense may well have been no worse in countries like Brazil than in the US in the early days of industrialization. But here without cleansing the state of the Latifundia (the landed interest), Brazil could not pursue clear policies to abet the industrial transformation, and therefore the governance of the state may be said to have been dysfunctional. The issue of fairness is in this context entirely secondary. Conceivably in a state that is a coalition of various classes, chaos, and civil war (which may appear as governance failure), that leads to ridding the state of the older classes which stand in the way of bourgeois transformation may well be functional even if the process is seamy and abhorrent.2 RUSSIAN MAFIAS The Soviet system collapsed as an organization and ideology completely, and no organized (controlled) transformation to the market economy was possible, because every moment of confusion and anarchy only reduced the prospects of any such orderly transition. Having stayed long in that disorganized state, the mafia that is today organizing production, markets and firms, ca nnot be seen as entirely dysfunctional even if their particular actions are abhorrent. The only system that can in itself emerge out of the present chaos without great leadership and central organization is the capitalist, with all its negative aspects. And the m afia plays a positive if violent role in that birth. 1 That these may have served to secure the right to private property of the bourgeoisie against the propertyless is quite clear. In a slightly earlier period, the bourgeoisie had won the right to property against lords and rulers with political power. 2 Thus the brutal Syngman Rhee’s regime in South Korea got rid of the landed interests, including rich peasants form the power base, and virtually eliminated the left wing to create a state that was just right for industrialisation in the hands of ‘strongman’ Park Chung Hee. 18 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 2.2 Corruption in China FROM PARTY TO BOURGEOISIE The comparison and contrast of corruption in India with China is important. Corruption today (or rather yesterday) in China is no less than it is in India. Indeed, we may succinctly describe China’s process of growth and evolution into a capitalist society since 1979 as one uninterrupted orgy of corruption, in which party functionaries (both the executive and the bureaucracy) fully exploited both their political power as well as, their power over economic decisions and state-owned enterprise. The latter happened especially after the managers in SOEs were allowed profit shares. Thus, the near complete egalitarian (in an economic sense) society of Mao has now evolved into a society with some inequality. The transformation of the party elite (even lower rungs) into a bourgeoisie is, from the vantage point of its functionality to the industrial transformation, akin to the junkers turning capitalists in Germany in the 1860s after several years of the Zollverein. So an entire bourgeoisie is being created out of the party members, but especially its elite. Besides corruption per se another aspect in the accumulation has been the round haul of Chinese capital via Hong Kong, Taiwan, Singapore and the US (via non resident Chinese many of whom are relatives of party officials), that mistakenly gets reported as FDI into China.1 What goes on today cannot be described as primitive accumulation per se. The phase of primitive accumulation of Marx, in China was (under socialism) during the period up to the mid-1970s, especially during the Great Leap Forward. And this accumulation fits the idea of primitive socialist accumulation of Preobrazensky. In Russia that phase was in the 1920s and 1930s. Unfortunately for Russia, it actually went ahead with creating a socialist society. The Second World War by its appeal to Russian nationalism prevented the contradictions of the socialist 1930s from being fully exposed, and the Cold War that followed only increased the resolve of the state and party to not question its basic assumption of a transformation without markets. The phase in China from 1979 to date can be termed as one of re-emergence of capitalism and markets on the sound basis (of endowments for all) provided by nearly thirty years of communism.2 The market had not been completely destroyed under communism (unlike in Russia), and agriculture was the first to be liberalized. Therefore, consolidation of the market mechanism was not at the cost of the poor. Indeed, the consolidation of private property in the first phase was that of peasants which was followed by that of lower rungs of the party who set up petty businesses, and then that of the elite sections who then went on to accumulate capital through not entirely fair means. In simple language power and money cannot be divorced for too long. Similar processes came about very early, with independence, in many of the African countries variously described as bureaucratic, kleptocratic or state capitalist (Mamdani, 1976; Shivji, 1976; Leys, 1975). In India too at the state level through mechanisms such as the joint sector and surpluses from agriculture and rents from the state, a local bourgeoisie has emerged. Thus, capitalism shows corruption as an integral aspect when the bourgeoisie emerges. To the extent that the Indian bourgeoisie (however stunted) has had an early origin3 (perhaps even earlier than the Japanese), and shows an intermittent growth thereafter, there is no dramatically distinct phase of their emergence. But the 1980s and the 1990s (until 1996) may be seen as consolidation through profit and rents. CORRUPTION HAS SUDDENLY BECOME DYSFUNCTIONAL The question that naturally arises is why is the Chinese system so actively and purposefully coming down on corruption today, when over the last couple of decades it not only turned a blind eye, but also may have actively encouraged the same? The answer lies in the returns to corruption, which have come down with growth and maturity of the economy, and the creation of a now numerous class of capitalists. Corruption which was functional yesterday to the accumulation and capitalist development is no longer so as the economy moves to a higher level of development wherein further corruption would mean eating into each other’s profits. What was observed in the US in the 1920s when corruption was finally tackled, is happening today in China but a lot more suddenly. If freedom from corruption and a legal basis for commercial interaction are treated as goods, their consumption by the masses (non-participating in corruption) is now possible, since the incomes of the masses are above that minimal level and they can resist corruption. Given the extreme equality of Chinese income distribution, that transformation is sudden. In white goods and telephones the growth in consumption has been stupendous for the same reason. The very high growth rate of the economy is another aspect of the same phenomenon, since that high growth rate is itself inter alia a result of the equality of income distribution. TRANSFORMATION SUCCESS IS DUE TO ENDOWMENTS The big question is why despite this massive corruption has there been no governance failure in the functional sense, that is, a failure leading to the slowing down of the industrial transformation? To answer that question is to explain the late industrialization 1 2 It is known that about 80 to 85 per cent of Chinese FDI (average US $ 40b in the late nineties) are Chinese investments from these countries. The cultural revolution, may have been a set back in more ways than one since it took attention away from the task of accumulation. It may have also have made China critically short of certail skills like managers and bankers that it required for modern economy. 3 Even if we keep aside the early modern industrialists like Dwarkanath Tagore and others c.1860–70, whose valiant efforts fizzled out due to a hostile colonial state, there were others like Tata and Birla who came in a few decades later. (See Dutt 1911). The Challenge to Governance in India 19 of East Asia, and this report is not the place for it.4 It suffices to say that all of East Asia grew very rapidly because of land reforms that were carried out in South Korea, Taiwan and Thailand (less critical since land is more plentiful) and in China and Vietnam (both under communist rule). Such reform released the home market constraint. AND TO EXPORT-ORIENTED POLICIES Additionally, pursuit of export-led growth (China from 1979) to overcome the foreign exchange constraint and to add to demand was the key. Successful economic transformation has therefore nothing to do with good corruption free governance as is the general belief, but is necessarily about getting the initial conditions (essentially economic) right, if need be through political action. It is certainly not caused by culture and such other sociological factors including the tautological work ethic. The work ethic itself would have been the result of success in the economic task of transformation.5 The essential initial condition is really that the majority of people is endowed to be able to participate in the market as producers and workers, and hence as consumers. All other aspects are really secondary or endogenous to the process of transformation itself—work ethic, life style, entrepreneurial firms, technological development etc. This is not to deny some autonomy to large firms, the state and others via strategic investments in areas of market failure to speed up the transformation process. RENTS BECOME CAPITAL IN CHINA The vast impetus to growth in China following the relaxation, or non-existence of the home market constraint, and the pursuit of export-led growth means that rents have a high probability of being invested, and thus, that surplus (though rent in origin) becomes capital and not directly unproductive activity (DUP), as is the case with economies like India, with severe demand constraints. At investment rates of 40 per cent6 plus and growth rates of above 10 per cent (till the recent slow down to 7.5 per cent) all sources of surplus including those illegal have the functionality of speeding up the transformation process because they are invested. When investments in India are as low as 26 to 28 per cent with a marginal savings rate close to 40 per cent but average around 25 to 27 per cent, the economy is demand constrained. So the problem in India is not rents per se, but that so little of it is invested back into the economy. Not only that, so little of even profits may be invested given the current strangle hold of conservative macroeconomic policy. Capital flight and avoidable waste in DUPs and other activities emerge to bring about the current equilibrium, and that creates its own ethos of a lazy rent seeking and rent wasting economy, with vast inequalities. 4 See Morris, S. (1997) for the argument that export-led growth is not laissez faire, but is the purposeful, promotion of both import substitution and export promotion at the same time, through a highly undervalued currency. Earlier, economists like Lall (1994), Datta Chaudhury (1981), Alam Shahid (1989), Amsden (1989) had argued that the states’ direction, and active involvement were important. 5 Who would have talked about ‘Confucian work ethic’ in the twenties after a visit to Shanghai or Taipei of the day? 6 Doubts have been raised about the stability of the Chinese banking system. In comparison to that of most other countries they seem to be so stretched that they could come collapsing like a house of cards. If growth slows down to less than 5 per cent then the problems of the banking system would have to be sorted out. What is generally not known is that late industrialization, because it offers the scope to grow very rapidly, also allows higher debt–equity ratios and higher proportions of borrowed capital to own capital, without increasing bankruptcy risk. This is because few industries face fundamental uncertainty. And with a strong state even that residual risk can be minimized. China is merely following on the footsteps of Japan, South Korea and Taiwan, of high financial repression of the economy. That strategy is today functional to the Chinese economy. It is entirely incompatible with convertibility on the capital account. South Korea, Taiwan and Thailand had opened themselves on the capital account in the 1990s. That was the real cause of the currency crisis, since Japan in an earlier period had pulled through this risky financial strategy to great advantage by delaying its convertibility till well after its complete industrial transformation, that is, only in the 1980s. are in the majority. Standard notions of dimensions of good governance—participatory, transparent, and accountable—may be limiting. Only propertied citizens (but not people in general)5 may be able to take advantage of such good governance. The aspect of class is of particular concern in India because of the prevailing inequalities of incomes. It brings in a whole new dimension to governance. It makes any meaningful characterization of governance inseparable from the nature of the state and its class basis. Even in democracies where theoretically the poor have the 5 Our contention therefore is that, growth which takes all people above that survival level of income has to have primacy over all else in a capitalist society, as the goal of policy and practice in all poor countries. same political rights and privileges as the rich, the economy rules to corrupt, distort, and ritualize many political processes such as participation. Stability to such discordant societies is provided by an escape route for sections of the politically ambitious (climbers) even among the poor. Thus powerful big-men in democratic Kenya, India or Bangladesh quickly amass wealth by controlling the levers of power. And this small window that allows a few (outside the elite) to convert political power into wealth has been wellrecognized as a characteristic feature of such societies.6 That process, an important aspect of which is corruption of public offices is very visible, attracts media attention 6 Mamdani (1976), Leys (1975), Shivji (1976) 20 India Infrastructure Report 2002 and is much discussed. It is actually an important process for the survival and the continuation of the hold of the elites over a vastly in-egalitarian society. This kind of politics cannot be corrected by urging politicians not to be corrupt. As law makers it is easy for them to create laws with loopholes that make the space for them to indulge in corruption. The cure actually lies in growth and development, which in taking people above a certain level of income quickly would create the right atmosphere and basis to stand up against corruption.7 Meaningful good governance is very difficult in such discordant societies. In such a society which is also truly democratic as in India (a rarity since discordance is usually managed by authoritarian regimes), the fact of political corruption and anomie, should not lead to the policymaker losing hope. The point really is to look beyond corruption, to the leverage points for change in society. These lie principally in getting the initial conditions for industrialization right—a population in which everyone has some (minimum) endowments, so that individuals can participate as both producers as well as consumers. Today that would translate to land reforms and security of tenure to the cultivator. It would also mean appropriate macroeconomic policy giving primacy to growth. In short, policy and politics become the drivers. In a more limited sense though, institutional change towards better organizations and rules provide an opportunity today in India, since there is a broad consensus that reforms should continue. Only with a more egalitarian income distribution can governance hope to be both functional and good. INSTITUTIONS, ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, GOVERNANCE IN INDIA AND Prior Institutional Development in India India, which started out with nearly all the institutions (largely inherited from the British) current in advanced societies, but limited to serve only a miniscule proportion of its population, failed in the apparently easy task of simply extending the domain, and access to these 7 One may ask: How can growth take place when such politicians stand in the way of good policy and its implementation? While there is no doubt about the influence of this corrupt behaviour on the policy and economic management, our contention is that at this juncture, all that the corrupt politician demand is an ‘illegal’ share. It is possible for wise policy to result in high growth , so that the costs of accomodation can be borne. The ‘rents’ that they would collect while no doubt unfair and possibly illegal would if invested make this ‘outside’ politician a capitalist. The resulting governance and state system would be functional but not fair. Thus we would caution those who want to change governance to work through the economic rules of the game. institutions, to the whole of society. Today we know that in India such extension has been more formal than real. In contrast, East Asian societies starting out without the institutional benefit of the colonial yoke, were able to create institutions as they went along and as the need arose. This raises the question: can the early existence and growth of institutions, much before their need in an economic sense, prove premature and reduce the prospects of the transformation? Possibly yes, if the history of South Asia in the second half of the twentieth century is any indication. The Failure of India India had all the ingredients by way of rules, institutions and organizations in spheres such as law, politics, participation, administration and governance, which few other non-industrial countries had. It also opted for universal franchise and a ‘fair and true’ democracy, which meant that most of the inherited institutions and more had to be extended to cover the entire population. Did the costs of such extension prove backbreaking for the immature economy? Could these have in any case been avoided? We must recognize the massive bureaucratic overburden that has resulted, with the economy having to support an extensive state apparatus that in form is concerned with institutional development.8 India because of its ‘failed’ economy cannot in reality claim to be (although in form the claim can be made) successful even in the political front. Political and social institutions tend to show the form of success and correctness but not the content and substance. Constitutionally provided decentralization exists in theory but is negated by government rules, orders processes and controls, and overstaffing; caste equality is enshrined in the constitution but violated every hour in some corner of the country. Equality of opportunity is enshrined in the Constitution but poor children out of school, and others not so poor are exploited in Bihar and UP by a rapacious private sector because public schooling has all but collapsed. Indeed, an entire enterprise has evolved within and outside government whose task is to manage the contradictions between the formal political and social 8 Yet, there is no denying that had economic growth been as rapid and broad-based as was envisaged by the planners and the founding fathers of the nation, this burden may perhaps have been not as onerous as it is today. Could the prior institutional development then have been an asset? Perhaps so, and in that case India may well have been able to complete both its economic, and social and political transformations simultaneously! Today East Asia (including China with its economic transformation just round the corner) await their political and social transformations with a very good chance of completing both. Thus in a causal sense the explanation shifts to the failure of planning in India, which is principally due to the neglect of land reforms, and the export pessimism of the plan models. The Challenge to Governance in India development on the one hand, and slow economic development on the other, and the consequent non-realization of political and social development in substance. Thus, for the state it is important to tell the intelligensia and the middle classes that it (the government) is doing something about poverty and the environment; that it provides scholarships; that it has hundreds of special and targeted programmes, that there are many thousands of nongovernmental organizations or NGOs working in the villages and elsewhere, and that there are free hospitals; free water supply; and that all are equal before the law. In truth though, despite all these efforts, India has very slow growth in per capita income barely doubling over a thirty year period (and not because of a high population growth as many believe to be). It also has one of the worst records with respect to the environment. Bright young boys and girls are systematically excluded from good education given its highly elitist character (despite the activities of charitable and religious organizations). The leakages from government programmes are so large, ranging from a minimum of 30 per cent to as high as 98 per cent, that such programmes are more usefully (and correctly) seen as programmes that serve to buy up potential dissent among the excluded and deprived. Despite free hospitals, even the poor spend vast sums on medical care; health status and morbidity of the Indian is amongst the worst in the world. We have tragically (and shamefully) the highest incidences of avoidable diseases such as blindness and mental retardation due to vitamin deficiencies, leprosy, tuberculosis, typhoid and malaria to name just a few. Criminal suspects are often subject to inhuman treatment by the police in the process of extracting a confession. At the same time drunken driving by affluent individuals resulting in fatal accidents may go unpunished. Often the police themselves play a role in supressing evidence. The institutional school would explain economic performance in terms of institutional inadequacies or their absence altogether. It is true that the two are intertwined. And any snapshot picture of poor economic performance would reveal inadequate or missing institutions. But this does not mean that institutional failure was a cause of poor economic performance. In fact poor economic performance, leads competing groups and interests to focus more on how the cake is to be divided that is, on redistribution rather than growth and transformation. This results in the populist politics, and the corruption that has now virtually destroyed many institutions. We will examine how, given the mess, attempts to correct the same through institutional efforts have usually failed in the past. Nevertheless, in a limited sense, reforms have created the space for institutional change and successful governance inprovements. With time if nothing is done, this window of opportunity could close. 21 Failure of Endogenous Attempts in India The Administrative Reforms Committee (1970) made very valuable recommendations even though in the light of present-day understanding of the bureaucracy they look rather staid. They have the limitation of being a purely administrative approach to improve administration, rather than any major shifts towards an increased role for the market. Nevertheless most of the recommendations were not taken up and the few that were, were ritualized to a point where no real difference was made. Similarly there is a Department of Administrative Reforms and Public Grievances. What they do is hardly known to citizens or even to most government officials. Similarly other administrative and organizational reforms have been attempted many times in India without much success, pointing to the entrenched nature of the dysfunctionalities, and their basis in the character of the state, and the overriding dominance of the bureaucracy without a concomitant accountability.9 The measures recommended for change, whatever the intentions or assumptions of their original designers, mutated and got ritualized to end up reinforcing the mess that was sought to be cleared. MoUs (Memoranda of Understanding signed between Public Sector Undertakings (PSUs) and government, the mechanism of the holding company as a buffer between PSUs and government were all instituted to reduce dysfunctional interference of the government in PSUs, and thereby to give mangers the requsite autonomy and accountability for performance improvement. They worked elsewhere, notably in France, but in India they got ritualized and continue to exist on paper with no real effect on distancing PSUs from government (see Box 2.3). Political Economy of Design Failure Many well crafted ‘fine institutions’, have deteriorated. Examples would be the state schools education machinery, health delivery systems and government purchase (including defense purchases10). Why? Deficiency in design is only a small part of the explanation.11 It is more likely that the underlying root causes are the overall environment of corruption and rent seeking, minimal accountability given 9 The lack of accountability resulting from the structure of the bureaucracy, the civil servants’ significant power, and their relationship with the political executive is well understood. We cover some of this when we discuss the failure of the Panchayats later. 10 This is based on the author’s own professional study of the system of purchases for the armed forces of such things as uniforms, tentage etc. 11 The solution though may still be in correction of these deficiencies when there is a strong motivation and willingness to change! 22 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 2.3 Institutional Efforts for PSU Management Fail MOUS FAIL In the area of public sector management, (which is recognized as a major aspect requiring governance related assistance, by the World Bank and others), measures such as the holding company or the MoU got entirely ritualized.1 They ended up becoming an added expense and a distraction and did not in any way reduce government’s dysfunctional interference in companies (the original purpose of the MoU). The reasons for such a pass are well known. Until the budgetary squeeze on the PSUs, there was little need for any of those in positions of decision making to change. The dysfunctional interface allowed displacement of responsibility, provided for hidden budgets for the politician to use, reduced the challenge for senior managers, allowed workers high wages and security with very little work, and to even translate their vast bargaining power into idle time. The private industries that benefited from the relatively low prices of PSU products could not complain. The MoU over the late 1980s and early 1990s had got reduced to a ‘complex document’ crafted by the ‘Adhoc Committee’ within the Department of Public Enterprise, in consultation with the enterprise and low level functionaries of the administrative ministries. They were evaluated by a ‘High Powered Committee’, which could never have had the time. The entire exercise was purely formal. The essential seriousness attached to an important contract was not there. They were seen more as an academic exercise than as a binding contract. No rewards and punishments were attached to either performance or adherence, or to their absence. It was not in any way negotiated. Soft targeting was rampant. It is doubtful if any of the administrative ministries thought of themselves as being constrained by the MoUs. Yet MoUs spread like wild fire and nearly all PSUs today go through a MoU annually. We have, what the French have most effectively used, viz the contract form to distance the PSUs from government, but sadly only on paper. SO DO HOLDING COMPANIES Earlier we had started with another form, the ‘holding company’, to create behemoths like the Steel Authority of India Limited (SAIL), Bharat Bari Udyog Limited (BBUL). SAIL was the creation of the late Mohan Kumaramangalam, the dynamic young steel minister who, in being close to the Prime Minister Ms Gandhi could cut through red tape. He was particularly enamoured by Fabian socialism and the Italian holding companies. During his leadership SAIL did manage some autonomy, but since his death, SAIL has been a curious and tragic mix of a bureaucracy and a ‘managerial hierarchy’, that is parasitic on the steel plants at Bhilai, Bokaro and elsewhere. The reform of SAIL would mean that not only government gets off the back of the steel plants, but even the top heavy SAIL head office is wound up. SAIL had the ridiculous distinction of employing 220 thousand people to produce some 8 million tonnes of steel, when Pohang Steel of South Korea (POSCO) could produce the same with just 13000 people. Similarly, in a still earlier period organizations like the Project Implementation Board (PIB) set up within the Planning Commission to coordinate the investment decisions of the PSUs, ended up to become a millstone round their necks. In its own direct actions the PIB may have been responsible for much of the delays and cost overruns in public sector projects. The Planning Commission itself is an organization that ritually plans, when government itself hardly takes these plans seriously.2 1 This is now well accepted. For a Discussion on why MoUs as also holding companies were failing when they were being actively implemented see Morris (1990). 2 For a discussion on how PIB and other institutional oversight delayed investment projects and brought about cost overruns, see Morris (1989). the nature of defined government processes and rules, and the politics of displacement between authority and responsibility. Also the open invitation to corruption in the form of ‘lowest cost tenders’, zero feedback and punishment of errant bidders, absence of processes to blacklist such vendors have together been responsible for the heinous crimes committed in public hospitals. This has been brought out by the Lentin Commission Report (1988). Correcting such ‘bloomers’ in design involve change at the core of government processes, hardly possible without a movement, and strong economic and political pressures to correct them. Dysfunctionalities of Worthy Institutions Similarly, in the context of public management we do have the institution of the Controller and Auditor General (CAG) whose job is to selectively audit the use of public money, that is, inter alia perform ‘CAG’ audit of PSUs.12 It has rarely exposed cases of the big misappropriations and corruption. But most managers would generally agree that it has restricted entrepreneurial initiatives in PSUs, to the point of rendering managers impotent. Despite audit, the corrupt can always get away by covering their tracks. Today Vigilance has emerged as a major constraint to entrepreneurial initiative in the PSUs. It is not so much the case that the institutions of the CAG and the Chief Vigilance Officer (CVO) and the roles they play are per se dysfunctional in a democracy. But given the failure of the other systems, these have resulted in pervasive 12 This is in addition to commercial audit under Company Law (statutory audit). The Challenge to Governance in India governmental interference at the operational and managerial levels in PSUs. Neither audit nor vigilance is able to work without large costs within the system. The general point is that even the best institutional forms, without underlying change in the politics and in the environment of the organizations whose improvement is sought, is of no avail. To bring about effective change the very existence of the organization and the status quo has to be threatened.13 So in a policy sense addressing governance directly without at the same time creating the political and economic conditions is pointless and a mere ritual. We will argue that unlike the past, in some sectors today, such conditions either exist or are about to be realized, so worrying about governance and design at this juncture is useful. Thus liberalization and the budgetary squeeze on state owned enterprise all create the right conditions for correcting design errors. MODE OF SUBSIDIZATION AND CORRUPTION The reform process thus far has eliminated the vast rents that were generated through licences, controls and shortages. This does not not mean that rents are not generated today. Poor administration of subsidies, contracts contrary to public interest, and residual shortages especially in infrastructural services continue to remain, feeding corruption and governance failure. We conclude the section by arguing that only with the policies that remove the scope for rents and with the correct modes of delivery of subsidies can governance improve. Today subsidies are under attack, and there is much consciousness among reformers that they need to go. I had argued that more than a sharp reduction in subsidies a ‘stepping stone solution is called for.’ By shifting from existing modes of subsidization to direct subsidization can, not only plug the leakages and improve condition for governance, but also lead to conditions whereby reform can become decoupled from the bind of subsidies. Herein we take the case of electricity and argue the point already made, in greater detail. The discussion on the oil sector (see Box 2.4) exposes the mess that has resulted from the current mode of diesel and kerosene subsidization. In moving from current modes to direct subsidies, there would be much support for the reform from politicians who truly represent the interests of farmers. It is in the realm of political possibility. Nothing 13 This is a fairly universal phenomenon. Large organizations, public and private (when not run by a small group or an individual), or in other words, bureaucratic organizations have rarely responded to opportunity. It is ‘threats’ that have had success in bringing about organizational change. The detailed case study of the Imperial Chemical Industries (ICI), U.K. brings out all the nuances (Pettigrew 1985). 23 could help major infrastructural areas like electricity, water and irrigation more than direct subsidization. ‘Agency Failure’ Due to Different Prices The current mode of subsidization (financing the deficit of State Electricity Board or SEBs by transfers or simply allowing them to mount) creates an invitation to corruption that is, surprisingly, not universally recognized. Thus the SEB managers report high T&D losses when a large part, usually more than half, is theft or leakage, where the manager himself is involved in underhand sales usually to small industrial consumers and affluent households using air conditioners. Similarly, SEBs over-report auxiliary consumption. Perhaps more importantly, the manager overreports sales to the subsidized sectors when in reality he would have sold to industrial consumers, and created rent equal to the quantity so sold times the price difference.14 This is a situation of rents with losses (Pandey, Section 6.3). The leakages that so result are very large. Thus, in Gujarat in 1995, had the leakages been plugged, the Gujarat Electricity Board or the GEB whould have shown a profit of over 20 per cent on equity rather than a loss of 20 per cent! In other words unlike the belief of many consultants, the problem with electricity prices is one of irrational pricing rather than a lower average price. This kind of pricing creates the ‘open invitation to corruption’ in the delivery systems. Both irrationality in the price structure and the leakages can be stopped with direct subsidization. Direct Subsidy and Reform With direct subsidization, the electricity company (SEB or its inheritor) sees uniform prices (regulated or part-determined in the market for wholesale power) since the subsidized customers pay with coupons (encashable) and with cash above their entitlements. All zones or circles except the very remote and sparse ones become viable for private investment. Reform can now take off overnight in various ways—reform by mere corporatization of SEBs, by privatization of distribution-cum-generating companies, or through markets for wholesale power. The company, within the ceiling imposed by the regulator, could offer differential prices based on the need to maximize its profit. Possible outcomes are low prices for agriculturists since many of them would not mind consuming electricity at off-peak hours. Similarly industrial customers with the ability to shift demands to off-peak hours could get electricity at low prices. Invitation to Governance Failure and Corruption I had argued that reform in the electricity sector has to start with direct subsidization for the farmer and other 14 These were brought out in detail in Morris (2001a). 24 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 2.4 Creating Governance Failure in the Oil Sector SUBSIDIZATION AND ADULTERATION In 1979, after the second oil shock, retail prices of petroleum products were increased due to the imposition of heavy duties. There was, consequently, a need to cushion the shock on diesel and kerosene. Farmers were important users of diesel and poor households used kerosene. Soon enough, the tax demands on the sector and the cross subsidization within the sector grew. By the late 1980s, the final price of petrol was way above other fuels. Till recently, the price ratio between petrol and diesel was as high as 3:1, with naphtha higher, and with kerosene in the range of 4:1. Even a 10 per cent adulteration of petrol with naphtha or certain solvents including benzenes generates stupendous profits in relation to the contract profits in the retailing business. The government pushes contracts (on paper) on to retail oil dealers that are so finely calculated that returns for honest dealers is about 16 per cent on assets.1 But ‘honest’ dealers are a rarity today. DEALER SECTION BOARD Companies do not have autonomy in the selection of dealers. A ‘Dealer Selection Board’ exists but the criteria for selection of dealers seems to have no bearing with the potential to perform well in the retail business. The Board itself is highly politicized. Why should a business yielding only modest profits be so much in demand? Most dealers are politically connected; some perhaps only a front for small time politicians. Dealerships are seen as payoffs at the lower levels of the political system. There are also the usual reservations for ex-soldiers, handicapped people, depressed castes, freedom fighters, and other worthy citizens. But many allotees are fronts for the real operators who control several outlets. Corruption is rampant and the marketing departments of oil companies cannot avoid being involved. The extent of corruption varies much across regions. It is generally believed that the extent of adulteration/short selling is more along highways, and more generally in the north and in Gujarat. ‘INNOVATIONS’ IN ADULTERATION Benzenes, naphtha, other solvents, and certain additives to keep the anti-knocking properties of the fuel within the required range for IC-engines with ignition, are used. There is actually much R&D that takes place in the small scale industry to develop such additives. There is major adulteration of oils, even in the lubricants trade especially 2T oils with improperly recycled oil. A licensed small industry has come up to extract base oil from used lubricants. But instead of doing just that, they manufacture lubricants with improper additives. Even the extraction processes are not good enough to completely remove the metal residues in used lubricants. This finds a ready and lucrative market among unscrupulous retail outlets and road side garages that service two wheelers. Branded pouches introduced by the oil companies have not restored confidence. The informal sector responded with similar-looking pouches. Since the freeing of lubricants from the administered price mechanism, specialist lubricant ‘super markets’ located all over and (significantly) away from fuel outlets have emerged. They do roaring business because nobody trusts retail outlets to sell clean lubricants, and the advertisements of the oil companies have helped build the scare and the consciousness. CREATED NEGATIVE ‘EXTERNALITY’ The consumers of petroleum products bear large private costs due to the adulteration and short measuring. Loss of engine power and life, more frequent maintenance, and considerable drop in mileage are the obvious effects. The social costs are enormous. When kerosene and solvents are used, it releases unburnt residues and monoxide in the exhaust. Many of the solvents and benzenes are hetero-cyclical and highly carcinogenic. Mere reporting of SO2 levels, as is done by the media in their pollution watch, does not capture this pollution. Despite multipoint full injection or MPFI, Euro-II and other standards adulteration goes unchecked in the cities. Indeed it is so rampant that a special auto-fuel is available on the streets of Ahmedabad at a fraction of the price of regular petrol. This is a mixture of petrol, benzene and possibly naphtha that makes each autorickshaw a pollution bomb. In highly corrupt and poorly coordinated societies such as India the notions of rent and directly unproductive activities may not be adequate to understand the economic effects of certain activities. Thus, when as a result of corruption in government purchase, the official earns rents then it is only in a static, ceterius paribus sense that we may see it as unintended redistribution. Other effects that follow are the second order effects in the rents having contributed to raising the effective price of the product. Now if the official and his establishment work hard to obfuscate, to create processes that are responsibility displacing, (where attribution of blame is difficult), then all that work instead of being directly unproductive (wasteful) is actually ‘negative’. The feed back effects on the system can be enormous. So-called vigilance agencies then have to work harder. They could, over a period of time, have developed processes to give the semblance of being active (putting out a few cases of anti-corruption) while letting most others go. Their role then becomes one of keeping the system of rents getting out of hand. Thus it adds negative value to the economy, rather than being merely unproductive.2 1 2 Many managers claim that margins are purposely kept low to keep out good people! See Gupta and Morris in 3i Network 2001 who brought out the case of wanton deterioration that creates the scope for further maintenance activity on public roads. When railway projects are delayed, resulting in earthworks being washed away with the monsoon and have to be done all over again, the processes that delay may be seen as cause resulting in ‘negative value addition’. The Challenge to Governance in India WHY COMPANIES CANNOT DO 25 MUCH The government holds oil companies responsible and advises them to police the retail distribution business. The oil companies however, have no control over the dealers. Dealers do not admit to adulteration. They have a strong association, and when individual cases of adulteration are occasionally taken up, nothing happens. Additionally, the fine/punishment is too small for adulteration or short measuring. Based on the numbers of dealers actually caught adulterating or short measuring, it is estimated that at least 30 per cent of retail outlets, in the best of the nationalized oil companies are involved. It is probably worse for others. So what do the managers in the marketing departments really do? The rookies try to do something, fail, and ask for different postings. There is an interesting story of one such rookie, who is today a senior manager, finally opted out of marketing because he could not bear this systematic assault. In one South Indian city, where citizen awareness of the ill effects of adulterated fuel is somewhat greater than elsewhere, he launched a campaign, following two cases of adulteration and short measuring that was discovered by the company. The action against the two outlets was the severest possible under the rules—their licence was suspended for a while, and citizens were told why the retail outlets were closed. The local company officials were able to withstand political pressures, but the sales of the company went down because now consumers knew for certain that petrol had from the company had been adulterated. Other companies who had equally bad, if not worse, retail outlets benefited out of the demand shift. Petrol quality is not easily measured at the retail level. ‘MANAGING’ CORRUPTION Many managers get wiser and though not necessarily corrupt, begin managing the corruption rather than stamping it out. They help to keep the adulteration within limits, and open new (suboptimal from a national or company point of view) company outlets to check adulteration. How have consumers responded? In the case where the rents have been in part passed on to the consumers (as in the case of auto owners in Ahmedabad), they benefit, but there are huge social costs. Motorists, especially those with high performance modern engines obtain information about dealers and locate one who does not adulterate (hopefully there is one in every city!). Variation in sales between dealers can be high. Thus in Ahmedabad the one outlet in the city that does not adulterate (besides company pumps that are not conveniently located) sells as much petrol as 25 per cent of the total sales of petrol in the city by all outlets of the same oil company! Consumers with incomplete information are subject to great stress. Others journey long distance to inconveniently located outlets to get good petrol. Yet, all the outlets, some of them with sales as low as 80 klpm, apparently make money since so much bribe is paid or influence used to get these outlets. Marketing jobs (‘dipstick mending’ in oil companies as it used to be called) in the mid-1980s, used to be prized jobs. They are probably prized jobs even now since they oversee points of huge rent generation. So change cannot come from within the system. Consumers as usual do not have the necessary leadership institutions to argue their case. Oil companies pin their hopes on the abolition of the dealer selection board in the post administered price mechanism (APM) scenario. This may help in the selection of new dealers. However, the retail business is overcrowded, and in case of any conceivable rational reorganization, many retailers would have to be closed as competitive margins and pricing emerge unless adulteration and short measuring continues, with the effect of upping the margins and creating over-entry. So how can one control and manage a set of dealers who have been reared in corruption? Would the establishment of private sector oil distributing companies (or privatization of the oil sector) help? In a limited way they could if the private companies are allowed to use price to signal quality. Then the consumer would have to pay high prices, the difference between the price of good petrol and bad petrol being a return to asymmetric information for the oil company. Socially, this is suboptimal. The oil company too bears an unnecessary cost of managing two different types of outlets, and ensuring that adulteration does not occur in the high priced segment of the business. Unlike the public company it would have a motivation to internalize the benefits of adulteration, and sometimes to stop it if the company’s reputation is directly linked to its behaviour. But the temptation to adulterate may come once a name has been established. The essential difference though may well be that the punitive measures by the government or a regulator are likely to become credible against a private company, rather than a public one, since any displacement of responsibility has necessarily to be contained within it. DISTORTIONS BREED FURTHER DISTORTIONS Privatization or not, no real solution is not possible unless the vast differences in prices are eliminated. In the current scenario, only heavy punitive measures with a large probability of getting caught, would help (If one is small, the other has to high). Thus, something close to ten years imprisonment may perhaps work. Any attempt to solve the problem without correcting the price difference in the first place, (except for the stiff punitive type mentioned above) would only compound the problem and create other unanticipated distortions. The solution of a company owned and operated outlet that is currently being pursued could add to the costs of distribution, if the employees of the labour contractor were to successfully put pressure for regular employment within the company, and get the courts to their side. It also adds to an already overextended retail outlet network. Elaborate testing machines to ensure quality also add to cost.3 Besides testing equipment, tamper proofing comes at a high capital 3 Absolute assurance of non-adulteration is possible only with the installation of octane, and cetane testers for petrol and diesel respectively and other instruments, which are very expensive. 26 India Infrastructure Report 2002 cost usually not justified given the Indian factor price ratios. In any case if tests are not going to be used to punish, they become mere rituals or irritants, as the current PUC (Pollution Under Control) certificates in most cities have become. Value creation at retail outlets through groceries and medicines dispensation is no compensation and would not work if the core product remains a problem. CREATED VESTED INTERESTS A little over a year back, there was what seemed like an effort to clean up the mess. The so called Solvent Scam surfaced 4, to reveal that vast quantities of solvents including benzene and naphtha ostensibly supplied for industrial use were diverted to adulterate petrol. The huge quantities involved and the wide extent of the operations that spanned over five states was remarkable. The kingpin was a Gujarat-based entrepreneur who had organized the entire business, and had the backing of highly placed politicians, excise officials and possibly managers in the petrochemical plants. The evidence against him was very strong, and well built up by the oil company that was keen to make a serious effort to stop the adulteration. The usual methods of destroying and falsifying evidence somehow did not work in this case. However, the business had its supporters among the political bigwigs. A counter-case against the alleging company was filed. Police brought forth evidence that diesel meant for industrial application (which had a lower price) was being diverted for use in the transport sector. The oil company officials were quickly arrested and jailed. Bails were denied and personal harassment of the officials began. The best efforts of the company to get the officials released were of no avail. The company’s argument, which had much logic, was that they had been selling diesel to firms who had been granted licences for lower priced diesel by the Excise Department. Was the Excise Department working hand in glove with these benami firms to take advantage of the price difference? Then there was little that company officials could have done. They (the company) claimed that they were neither an investigating agency nor the police. The final outcome is not known. Was a deal finally forced on the Company? We would never know. BIGGER MESS In Delhi, a large part of the pollution was due to adulterated fuel use. When confronted with pollution even after Euro-II norms were introduced for car engines5, the Supreme picked CNG instead of going for low sulphur diesel for use in combination with modern diesel6 engines, and 4-stroke engines for two wheelers and autos using petrol. One of the reasons cited by the environmental pressure groups is that, being gaseous, it cannot be adulterated. This, in other words is an implicit admission that nothing can be done about rampant adulteration! If CNG really goes ahead in a big way we will have imposed a huge and avoidable cost on the economy. The correct solution would have been as stated above. The problem of adulteration could be overcome through removal of the incentive in the price distortions for adulterating, with stiff punitive measures. (Allowing the oil companies to do so). The matter of subsidization of those who use diesel and kerosene could have been easily covered through direct subsidization, not too different from the direct subsidization in the case of electricity. To us it is amazing that none of the actors, the government, the politician representing farmers, the oil companies, nor citizen’s groups have actively argued for the case of direct subsidization. 4 Much of this paragraph is based on the author’s discussions with persons who would not like to be named. See reports of the Solvent Scam e.g. Malekar (2000). 5 Which in itself was a success, See Pundir (2001). 6 See Section 5.6, by B.P. Pundir. subsidized sections (Morris 2001a). Direct subsidization was a system whereby farmers and others once identified could be regularly issued coupons through banks and post offices equal to their fixed entitlements, allowing them to purchase electricity from distribution companies. As a result, it is possible to separate the subsidization and reform of the sector (otherwise in a Catch 22 situation), and address both issues independently. Politically it makes sense on the part of reformers to not ask for removal of subsidies—always very difficult—but to attempt to target subsidies correctly. Such a change in strategy would bring the politically mighty farmers on the side of reform. And the vast gains out of reform would allow the burden of subsidies to actually go down. It was argued that such a move is not only desirable but also necessary for reform to make progress. The current proposals of the Government, to directly make good the subsidy claims of SEBs or their inheritor organizations obviously creates an incentive to over-claim and over-report subsidies, which finance departments or regulators can hardly cross-check. This motive would remain for private companies too, even if they have a motive to reduce and plug leakages. The difference would be that leakages would have been internalized. Additionally, such subsidization removes or minimizes the distortions in the use of electricity. We had also argued that if all farm subsidies are bundled and made available for various inputs, with the farmer exercising choice, then the vast distortions in the cropping pattern, input use and especially in misuse of scarce water and land would be reduced or eliminated. The gain to the economy would be The Challenge to Governance in India stupendous. This, to my knowledge has not been adequately addressed by agricultural economists. Arbitrage Opportunity With such a large ‘arbitrage’ opportunity available to SEB managers, why should they not succumb to temptation? Indeed if a few take advantage of the opportunity, with little or declining risks of getting caught, such corruption spreads like wild fire to become the dominant pattern, to appear almost like a characteristic or a propensity such as ‘Indians are corrupt’ or ‘all government officials are corrupt’, when indeed the problem is one of the system rather than at the individual level. Nor is the problem that of culture. So-called cultural explanation to15 many things economic, is in most cases vacuous, and cannot lead to a solution. Rents in Other Subsidies Besides these cases of electricity and oil retailing (see Box 2.4), there are many others of policy failure that have now resulted in powerful vested interests. Among them are foodsubsidies through the so-called ‘public distribution system’, fertilizer subsidy, irrigation pricing. In all these the problem is more one of policy design rather than one of policy objective. To subsidize or provide the incentive per se was not as much a problem, as the way it was being done. The failure is therefore intellectual rather than one of implementation, and as such the policy-makers, or rather the detailers who are to be blamed. Here the responsibility falls squarely on the upper rungs of the bureaucracy. The politician in India has been forced to carry a lot more of the blame for the current mess, than is legitimately attributable to him. The bureaucrat and policy-maker by their intellectual laziness bear responsibility for converting what would have been accommodation of various legitimate interest groups, into opportunities for rent and graft. Talking to senior and now retired civil servants who were intimately involved in the electricity and fuel sectors reveals that, the mistakes were genuine. Correction though has now come up against the wall of vested interests. Distortions Don’t Cancel This tendency to overcome rather than correct a past mistake, with another measure (which would itself, in due course, become another mistake), is rampant to policymaking in India. In fact, the system values officers within 15 A ‘cultural explanation’ of corruption or governance failure can only lead to the impotent position of ‘changing the culture’, something practically impossible. As a process, cultures change much after the economic characteristics such as rewards and punishments incentives, information, and control have changed. 27 the bureaucracy who can provide such compensating solutions, a point I had made in the last IIR (3iNetwork, 2001, p. 9). This trap of ‘overcoming’ one distortion with another is so ingrained in our minds that we are not even conscious of the real options. Even the media is unable to step out of that paradigm. The intellectual architects of the mess of electricity pricing or fuel pricing now, after their retirement, continue to be ‘successful’ advisers of reform, creating further mess and sweeping them under the carpet as they go along. The trifurcation of SEBs on paper merely to get an ADB loan, the Orissa model of reform, the current Compressed natural gas (CNG) solution to vehicular pollution in Delhi, the ‘coverage of subsidization’ and ‘subventions’ to the GEB (and other State electricity boards) by the state governments are all examples of application of this approach. We can expect to suffer their consequences in due course. Thus it is obvious today that if direct subsidization, or better subsidy administration were to come about, there would be a quantum improvement in governance. Similarly, in a market economy, interventions that recognize the constraints (and opportunities) in the market would also result in major positive changes in the environment for the improvement of governance. SHORTAGES AND CORRUPTION Unlike oil products or electricity, administered prices in other crucial products such as cement, paper, steel and non-ferrous materials were accompanied by control orders. Control orders served to manage shortages that would be inevitable in non-market prices. Thus ‘approved’ construction could hope to get steel and cement allotted at controlled prices, while the rest of the economy went either without these or had to pay ransom prices for these otherwise mundane products. The resulting impact on the economy and society was dramatic. Governments had to develop the allocative machinery that was to do the job ‘fairly’. And even when not, it had to appear to be fair. The bureaucracies that came about to manage the shortages were very large. In steel allocations alone, a few thousand people may have been involved. More importantly in vitiating the controls or the rationing system, rents were created. The marginal value of housing is considerable in situations of shortage, and the rents which cement and steel traders could extract out of the middle class who could afford to build houses were considerable. Licensed Shortages and Licence to Corrupt There was a time when nobody (other than institutions and public organizations) could get cement without having a contact in government, or bribing officials. What was true of cement and steel was also true of many other basic 28 India Infrastructure Report 2002 materials like paper, furnace oil, many chemicals, which were administratively priced and allocated. In other goods and services which were also controlled (either on price or capacity or both), but where automatic rationing through queuing was possible, the scope for petty corruption was enormous. Numerous examples come to mind—scooters till the mid-1980s, railway tickets, food until 1972, movie tickets till the end of the 1970s. Telephone connections till the liberalization of the 1990s, electricity connections even today in rural areas and small towns, water supply and sewerage services, bus services. Where the markets could adjust with fancy prices, such as in imported goods the damage to the society was perhaps limited to the rents that were generated out of a licence awarded to a favoured few, or the returns to smuggling. It is where rationing or queuing was necessary that the greatest damage was done, since all people waiting in the queue would have an incentive to try and get some of the product by bribery if he could afford to. The administrative machinery would be able to extract rents since the cost of waiting or denial, to many, would be considerable. Such conditions when they continue long enough can corrupt practically all in society, except the ‘stupidly’ honest person. Most of us do what our neighbours do, which is why accents, trends and fashions are possible in society. If a person’s probability to commit a corrupt act is a positive function of the number of friends and neighbours who are corrupt, then in situations with vast rent opportunity, long queues and shortages, it is only a matter of time before public moral standards fall and a so called corrupt culture emerges. Nearly all Indians would have given a bribe to a train ticket examiner or a village talati. The connected elite of Delhi would not even think that they are doing something wrong when they fix up for a fee somebody’s business with the government. As the control and allocation raj gave way in most manufacturing sectors, the problem of shortages and denial was overcome. Cement decontrol in the mid-1980s brought about massive expansion in output, lower prices and competition almost overnight. Today, personal bank credit, which was officially completely denied (or one had to find an accommodating bank manager who would pass off the personal loan as a lending to the small scale industry), is now available for the asking. For a brief review of the failure and success of India see Box 2.5. Infrastructural Shortages and Denial Remain However, in many infrastructural services, especially those consumed by the poor, the denial and shortages remain. It is easy to say that second class rail travel is underpriced and hence there are shortages. But true costs of passenger travel may not be substantially higher than that at present. Even at double today’s prices shortages would remain, since much peak season travelling is need-based. In railways, bus services etc., downward price elasticities are low (upward price elasticities may well be large in cases of travel for pleasure). Same is true of drinking water. In such sectors adjustments are made through inhuman overcrowding and congestion that the ‘unreserved’ traveler on railways and buses has to bear. Petty corruption naturally results since advance planning by definition cannot work for all when there is a shortage. Even more importantly in all municipal services but especially school education, water and sewerage, sanitation, street lighting, and roads, denial and shortages continue leading to corruption and neighbourhood competition. Many of these services being basic can be easily exploited by unscrupulous elements such as goons who organize slums, provide ‘protection’ and regulate water and toilet access or touts in railway booking offices, to extract rents out of the poor and those denied. Price elasticities are very low over a certain range, so price adjustments when possible are large enough to have (negative) income effects on the poor. Thus water market prices in areas denied adequate municipal supplies, slums and city outskirts are often close to the willingness to pay and typically many times the cost of production of these services. State Failure Compounds Market Failure Education, especially quality school education extracts large rents from even the poor and the lower middle classes. A shortage of good ‘English-teaching’ schooling makes harried parents victims of donation demands and high fees in the ‘new’ schools. Creating the ‘Culturally’ Corrupt Society Unlike the high corruption of the contracts variety—a la Bofors or Tehelka—corruption that an economy of shortages and administrative (non-transparent) allocation breeds is widespread and becomes almost universal. In society this petty corruption is often used to justify more dastardly acts of corruption. Thus when a young Indian Police Service (IPS) officer when after a few years of struggle to keep himself above the morass, finally gives up, he would use the argument that even his upright brother had to depend upon him to get that railway ticket or that ration card. Members of State Assemblies and the Parliament (MLAs and MPs) have quotas for gas dealerships and petrol-pump allocations, and earlier for telephone connection. There are VIP quotas on trains, quotas for certain worthy categories of citizens like doctors and shopkeepers. Also, higher level employees of organizations providing services have their own quotas to allocate. When these are priced and sold The Challenge to Governance in India 29 Box 2.5 The Indian Experience There have been significant improvements in social and economic well being since Independence, though nowhere near the progress made by East Asia and China. When the British left us, our average life expectancy was just 37 years for the country as a whole (Habib, Irfan, 1975). This means that vast numbers of the very poor (peasants) in Bengal, Bihar, Orissa, Eastern UP and Telengana would have had life expectancies no more than 25 years! A figure lower than that of Neanderthal man. Today life expectancy is nearly 60 years in some states. WHAT HAS BEEN THE SOURCE OF THIS PROGRESS? Much of the improvement in life expectancy has come from technological developments in vaccines (vaccine programmes can be administered even in situations of state failure), in antibiotics (especially cheap), and in some improvements in diet especially on account of the milk, vegetable and egg revolutions. Per head grain intake has gone up very little or has remained static if some of our food statisticians have to be believed. Even accounting for increased calorific intake due to potatoes in eastern India, it is unlikely that food intake has shown anywhere near the kind of improvement (from a better base) that East Asia has shown. This marginal improvement in food intake (and without any imports) would not have been possible without the High Yield Variety or HYV revolution, again largely technological and amenable to programme mode of extension without major demands on design of organizations. Public services continued to remain of abysmal quality and poor coverage, and may even have shown an overall deterioration in quality as these were over ambitiously sought to be spread. Similarly, social movements have had durable effects on both the society and the economy. These include the ‘Non-Brahmin’ movements of Southern India, including the Ezahava Rebellion in Kerala, the movement for the upliftment for lower castes and women by people like Jyotiba Phule and Ambedkar in Maharashtra, and ‘Sankritization’ processes in so far as they lead to lower castes valuing education. MICRO-INTERVENTION OF STATE HAS FAILED Microeconomic efforts at redistribution, by the state, began with vehemence since the stagnation of the mid-1960s, and has continued with increased emphasis ever since. This ‘massive’ redistributive effort has coloured and determined the very functioning of the government and the bureaucracy. Income distribution though has remained as skewed as ever. The proportion of the people below the poverty line is still explained best by the rate of growth in the preceding years, especially of agriculture. Action and organization for redistribution on the, part of the state has become an end in itself with the result being inconsequential. Thus, all these programmes spew out impressive ‘results’ which are defined in terms of expenditures (input measures) rather than effects (output measures1). Their real purpose we had mentioned earlier was to ‘buy up dissent’ and create the space for an expanding bureaucracy. Vast rents were no doubt generated in the leakages. We have already seen that those economies that carried out a one-shot (and economy-wide) redistribution of productive assets through land reforms (essentially a political and macro-process) have avoided altogether any continual redistribution on the part of the state. Thereby, they have been able to keep their state apparatus relatively lean and focussed on the task of industrial development. MACRO-PROGRAMMES In contrast to micro-intervention for redistribution, productively-oriented public investments, especially in irrigation, the HYV programme, higher education and primary education (to the extent this could be sustained) have had important effects. Similarly successful mega-programmes such as operation flood, and macro-efforts such as price support for food production (given the demand constraint for food) and subsidies (despite the waste) have had measurable impacts. (Subsidies have also dysfunctionally helped to create rents, which have over a period taken the form of ‘directly unproductive profit seeking activities’.2) The criticality of the growth of agriculture to the rest of the economy is not adequately appreciated. Agriculture and exports explain best the non-agricultural private sector GDP in causative studies (Morris, 1997). More importantly today (since the mid1970s) agricultural growth is constrained by inadequate demand requiring therefore a vast ‘buffer’ stocking. The only way the demand can come is by the poor peasant being unshackled enough to increase his output so that in producing he automatically creates demand. Only this can lead to a quick relaxation of the home market constraint for manufacturers. Thus land reform, or major income redistribution through massive food for work programmes in the Indian context today are the key issues that need resolution.3 To discard the present (conservative) regime of macroeconomic management for another more ambitious and expansionary is a live issue. The potential benefits in aggressive pricing of the currency and in interest rate targeting, if carefully managed are many. The high growth that it can bring, possibly in excess of 9 per cent, would be exhilarating. It would be the only way, not only to grow out of the current recession and the fiscal mess, but also go give the economy and society a fair chance to make its industrial transformation, and to therefore create the space and the pressure for governance improvements. 1 2 3 For a brief review of such programmes see K. Das in Section 7.1 in this report. A term due to Bhagwati, Jagdish (1982). Those are not excluded given the class basis of society, and of the state today. Land reforms as a capitalist strategy that enhances the home market, and embeds the institution of private property are feasible, if the Indian bourgeoisie can ‘think big’ to ensure its long term interests. 30 India Infrastructure Report 2002 for a fee as in the case of gas connections, then the damage to the moral and social fabric of the society is less, than when administrative discretion is actually used. Imagine a mother desperate to visit her ill son in a distant part of the country having no option but to cringe before a politician or a bureaucrat to get that ‘emergency quota’ released. Such processes deeply reinforce the notion that only contacts and administrative and political power matter in society, and therefore not ones work and rights. The notion of rights gets therefore muted, in all meaningful spaces of one’s ordinary existence. The pent up denial of rights can sometimes spill over on to the symbolic and political levels in a much destructive manner. This is not healthy for any democracy. It allows demagogues and charlatans to symbolically (rather than in substance) address the problems of the people. Thus Indian politics in caught in the rhetoric of symbolism, and in the complex web of contacts (the actual reality that cuts across party lines). A sustainable but expensive democracy results, were (harsh) realities do not matter because they are actively kept ‘hidden’, or ritualized to create sympathy rather than anger, reportage rather than analyses, and protest rather than revolution. CONTRACTS REGULATION AND GOVERNANCE Inappropriate Contracts The archetypal story here is that of Enron which had been dealt with in IIR 2001 and is also covered in this report. But our argument and that of several others including that of Sant, Dixit and Wagle (1995) who perhaps were the first to highlight the same, is that the IPP framework (despite the aspect of competitive bidding after a few ‘fast track projects were pushed through) has been flawed. In IIR 2001 and in the Infranet Conference December 2000 we had called for an immediate ban on all further IPPs and a withdrawal of all negotiations then on to bring potential IPPs to closure. Instead, we had argued for true reform based on open access to the transmission network and reform of subsidization. The details of the governance failure in the Enron saga have been brought out in its lurid details by Abhay Mehta (2000) whose facts have not been remotely contested even today despite the fact that his book has been in circulation for several years now, Prayas Group in this report (Section 6.7) brings out the implications for governance that arise out of the same. Here we are interested in drawing attention to a more general phenomenon within the government of refusing to right-staff key organizations and institutions of governance, causing failure as a result, and then shrugging away the whole thing as the cost of learning. Today lack of professionalism in key regulatory functions obstruct reform (see Box 2.6). Specialized Skills Besides the SEBI, many of the departments of the RBI, the Department of Banking, the Power Ministry, the DFIs and investment banks all need highly specialized knowledge and expertise that cannot be brought in by bureaucrats on the move, however clever and committed they are.16 The problem of policy-making and administration in a phase of transition to a liberal economy is perhaps most demanding and crucial. Once a successful liberal society has been ushered in, the challenge of governance perhaps reduces. But till such a point is reached governments have to work hard to create and adequately equip the new institutions, create enabling frameworks, such as BOT laws, and nudge consumer and other watch dog organizations into existence and activity. The failure of Indian governance in this front now threatens the continuation of reforms. There have been notable successes such as telecom reform, where the powerful force of technology overrode regulatory mistakes. Ports again have not done badly in this regard. Power sector reform has perhaps been the worst victim of this kind of failure. Private infrastructure needs credit enhancements, and hence may need to draw up elaborate agreements with the state. In some cases such contracts can be used to generate resources for the state without hurting the prospects for market development, and the interest of the consumer. In other cases such as that of the natural monopoly with little contestability and average growth prospects, it would be right for the state to grant subsidies and credit enhancements. There is no getting away from the fact that specialized skills such as knowledge of the sector and of laws relating to contracts, and technology, are the basis for the correct decision-making. What is desirable and suitable is not easily decided a priori in every context. Hiring consultants or bidding as a solution do not always work. Consultants’ knowledge can be very limited, and their best effort would not come forth unless the client is knowledgeable and well prepared.17 Bidding can result in optimal results only if the bid process is well structured, and that is not easy. It is not a generalist skill either. There are only limited gains in using consultants to correctly structure bids when government departments and authorities lack 16 For governance failures arising inter alia out of lack of specific knowledge and skills see Section 6.6 by S.K. Barua. 17 I have been witness to some entirely shoddy work done by consultants of international repute, since they knew that their client was ill-equipped to question them, and was not familiar with the task and the questions given to the consultants. The consultants had been covering up their poor work with jargon until the meeting in which a few better-informed people (all outside the government) could call off the bluff. The Challenge to Governance in India 31 Box 2.6 The Tragedy of Indian Administration There is no civil service training programme that I have yet conducted without encountering the civil servant blaming the politician. My standard argument against the futility and error in such blame, which has never failed to enliven the debate, is to show the ‘intellectual’ failure in many policies such as the export pessimism of Mahalanobis, inappropriateness of the mode of subsidization in many areas, Indian reformers having read export-led growth as laissez faire under World Bank tutelage, etc. I have tried to open the civil servants’ mind to other failures besides those attributed to vested interests of the politician. One could further argue how several politicians and the dysfunctional interests they represent are very much the result of past policy failure. Allied to these arguments I bring out the vacuousness of the often made statement ‘good policy but poorly implemented’, to argue as in IIR 2001, why that is a contradiction in terms—a good policy implements itself. MIXED-UP POWERS I go on to then reason why the Indian system is most failure prone. It is well known to a student of government that when executive decisions are the sole preserve of either a ‘bureaucracy’ (career bureaucrats in office), or that of elected politicians with clear demarcation of responsibilities and roles, then the outcomes in terms of governance and economic administration, have been far better than when both are involved together. The details of the Indian system are worth recounting from the bottom up. The lowest and perhaps most crucial levels of government (from the point of view of economic service provision) are the urban local bodies (nagarpallikas) and the village (gram) panchayats. They were always there but could never function effectively. It was hoped in a manner similar to that between the centre and the states, if the state could legislate the powers of the local bodies then things would begin to move in the direction of effective decentralization and hence effective local administration. Much hope was placed on the 73rd and 74th Constitutional Amendments that legislated the powers and functions of the rural and urban local bodies respectively. But that, it was soon realized, made no difference, since in any case local bodies had little fiscal resources of their own and depended much on the state government for much of their funds (Mathur 2001). It was again hoped that with financial devolution, as laid out by the state financial commissions, would result in autonomy and meaningful responsibility for local public services to local bodies. In many states the devolution has yet to be notified. Even where they have been, the results are not encouraging. The local bodies continue much as before, superceded for all practical purposes by state governments, officials and departments that work locally (Nanavati, 2000). This has happened because the bureaucracy in India is a true hierarchically ordered tree with no breaks to accommodate elected executives. Thus the talati, other clerks and junior officers view their senior officers at the district and state levels and not the panchayat president as their masters. Had the link in the chain of command been broken at levels where elected representatives were in executive positions, the embedding of responsibility would have been possible. Organizationally, most functionaries are being asked to serve two ‘masters’, when only one (the higher ranked official) is far more real, especially at the local level. Strangely, in having the Indian Administrative Service or IAS and other central services as a national cadre, the bureaucratic chain is not broken even at the level of the state, thereby denying the states (through the organizational aspect), much of the powers (and independence) they ought to possess under the Constitution. But the problem is far more serious at the level of local governments, where there is much displacement of responsibility: the elected representatives cannot be held accountable since they have no power over the officers and staff of the local body, and the bind of processes and rules can reduce them to impotence. The little financial autonomy they have compounds the problem further. The government employees on the other hand can hardly be made answerable to people. Elected representatives are at best able to influence the selection of beneficiaries of programmes pre-decided at the central or state levels, or be able to chose the site of a bore well, given that the state government or its parastatals have a bore well programme. Design and planning which start with the local problems of nagarpallikas is hardly possible. Local elections are highly politicized. This is entirely dysfunctional because local issues dominate the world of the citizen especially in rural areas and small towns. The politicization then becomes the excuse to tie the hands of the elected representatives in a maze of processes and rules. Similarly, the fear that panchayats may not adequately represent vulnerable castes, becomes an excuse to effectively bypass them in all targetted economic programmes.1 In that situation it is natural that the elected representatives turn to nepotism and graft. The scope for building political capital through good performance of the local bodies they head or are elected to is therefore limited. So what else can they do? The bureaucracy arranges for the graft, partakes in the same, and the system continues to exist and thrive at the cost of the people as a whole. So what systemic functionality do local bodies have? The expenditure on local bodies is not inconsiderable, and salaries and related administrative expenses absorb the bulk of their total expenditure. Therefore local governments of all but the larger towns may be nothing more than job creation by an expanding bureaucracy. Election of representatives in politicizing local opinion, deflects them from economic failure, by giving local leadership some participation in the ‘spoils’ of governance. Their potential to do good though is high if the local 1 In many parts of the country but especially in the south and the west, which have seen as neodicum of development, lower castes can no longer be systematically excluded by panchayats. In most situations that require the village as a whole to have an opinion, as in issues relating to displacement, natural disasters, road building, representative groups that include all castes have begun to emerge. 32 India Infrastructure Report 2002 bureaucracy can be made entirely answerable to the local elected representatives. Costs could go down dramatically, employment could then be more need and local requirement based rather than being derived from the rule book, and elected members would be empowered to be responsible. They and others would then not be able to able to pass the buck. COLONIAL ORIGINS OF THE ‘SYSTEM’ The origins of such a debilitating design lie in colonial rule. The reality of (British) Indian administration and governance was the governor general and the administrative bureaucracy that he commanded. The last authority in this hierarchy was the talati. As the pressures for popular government emerged (the reason for the freedom struggle), the British, as early as 1935, created legislatures at the provincial level with ministers and other elected officials, headed by Pt. Jawaharlal Nehru. This did not dilute the powers of the governors and the governor general in any substantial way. In such crucial dimensions of administration as the police, or district administration they retained complete control. With independence, while power over policy and law making shifted to the elected representatives, at the state and central levels the executive power is still shared between career bureaucrats, and elected officials. Only those politicians with great leadership skills and a natural flair for administration have typically been able to exercise their power in a positive manner. At the local level, where there is no legislative role, and little or no policy-making, executive power is the key, which is certainly not in the hands of the elected representatives. It may not even effectively be with the local officials since they could in turn be constrained by their own deep hierarchy, rule orientation, and dysfunctional role of the elected representatives. The collector remains the key authority at the district level and certain changes in the law such as the 73rd Amendment and the Land Acquisition Bill have only increased his powers. Such structures which obfuscate, and cannot allow for responsibility assignment can hardly be transparent or held accountable. Poor governance is therefore a problem of design but has its base in history. Its continues because of the elitist character of administration and society. THE BUREAUCRATS The following provides some generalized sketches of the more interesting types of bureaucrats one encounters. Of ‘Knights in Shining Armour’: Many capable bureaucrats (probably the best of the lot) revel in fixing problems. They are the means by which a minimum functionality of the system is ensured. They need the problems, as much as the vested interests who gain from the governance failures. They are shifted around when their activities become uncomfortable for the system. They are also sent in when things go wrong and have to be fixed or set right. They are usually incorruptible, clever, highly motivated individuals, with boundless energy. Unlike the ‘impotently honest’ bureaucrat they are able to take things forward. They have a particular knack for identifying problems, however uninteresting their posting. They also have a tolerance for extreme failures— either very large or very small. Thus, they are not reduced to impotence within the corrupt system. They are also able to get lower down functionaries, even corrupt ones, to work to their own plans. They may even look away in the face of petty corruption of their subordinates in the interest of overcoming the larger problem. They view every problem as something that must be actively corrected. They do not admit to systemic limitations. To them, if all bureaucrats were like them the system would be functional and good. That the system can have properties other than that of its individuals (holistic aspects, or in a more limited way, the idea of the fallacy of composition), has no place in their minds. They believe implementation failure is the main problem. Notions of incentive compatibility, functionality of the systems of rewards and punishments are anathema for them. Change arising out of social movements is also an alien idea. Some of them may see the solution in education reforms and modification of values. Change to them is what they and other energetic officers (and possibly some politicians) bring about. When they leave, their good work inevitably collapses. The stories of their success when narrated can be very inspiring and may lead us to believe that things could not go really wrong with such ‘knights’ around. A few may even be able to get into the limelight to become icons for the mass media and the middle class. And ‘Alchemists’: The more durable change comes from the ‘alchemist’ who understands the system and sees his role, not as a doer, but as one who releases or allows pent up forces to act. Such a bureaucrat or a politician sees policy not as something that needs to be implemented but that which implements itself. He would have no action stories to tell, and may appear academic . Unfortunately, his tribe is rarer than that of the knights. They have less romantic notions of their own roles and class, see themselves as ordinary individuals. Most bureaucrats who blame the system are not necessarily able to articulate the problem and leverage change, be it a law or a price distortion. The time to ponder is denied to them. Over time, they think that it is committees and expert groups (and today consultants) who should do the thinking. And Yet Impotence: A few of the alchemists who find time to think may also end up incapacitated. Freeing them is an important aspect of change. Armed with degrees in economics, management and public policy, they monopolize the entire thinking within the government. Their importance is particularly enhanced when reforms are on since they are able to put out papers, framework documents, drafts and white papers. Usually, their knowledge and understanding while very expansive, is not deep enough. There is little dialogue among them, since they are only the last leaves of an intellectual enterprise whose roots and big branches are in the west. In areas which require specialized knowledge or contextualization—electricity reform, revamping financial markets, monitoring banks, macro management of the economy, privatizing PSUs—despite their best effort the probability of design failure is high. The Challenge to Governance in India 33 INAPPROPRIATE CONSENSUS The process of consensus building around discussions of earlier drafts, usually kills the functionality of the final version that goes on to become the policy or law. The coherence of a particular approach is then lost. Such compromise papers are usually fatally flawed, and yet get pushed with the vigour that arises out of the bureaucratic and political processes that they would have gone through.2 To kill that bad idea becomes a tough task for those later responsible for the policy or law. 3 So even the alchemists who could have been agents remain constrained. Had the process of consensus building or compromise been in situations where compromise is possible (where for instance continuously varying solutions on some relevant dimension exists), and had the process been truly reflective of the interests of different segments of society, there would still have been some progress. To give an example: the mode of subsidization of electricity is not something that is to be decided on the basis of ‘bargaining’ or consensus. That has to be a ‘technical’ decision. To assume that it can be negotiated is to presume that thieves and rent seekers are sections of the interest groups. On the other hand the criteria for identification of the amount of entitlement (i.e. whether it ought to be largely a production, or an income subsidy), or the amount of entitlement itself, can be negotiated. 2 Practically, every major initiative, the BOT laws of state governments, the modifications to the Electricity Acts that created the regulators, the TRAI, the now pending Draft 2001 Bill on Electricity have been victims of this tendency. It was only the great technological dynamism of the telecom market, that was able to force changes to overcome the debilitating provisions of the earlier TRAI Act. See Jayanth Varma in Section 6.1 who brings out the fatal flaws in this ‘half way house’, in private financing. 3 Thus today reformers would have to ‘kill the IPP provisions’, the idea of subventions, extra charges on transmission usage as a cross subsidization devices, which were all bad ideas that came out of similar processes. basic knowledge of bids and the industry. Similarly, decontrol of highly regulated sectors is a delicate operation demanding skillful execution, if the creation of vast rents has to be avoided. Distancing from Government Additionally, it is crucial to distance such regulation, contract designing and policy formulation from the day to day affairs of the government for good governance. To illustrate the point, the formulation of a draft agreement, say for building sections of highways needs to be carefully done, widely circulated and commented upon, cross-checked and fully refined before it becomes official. But a specific agreement becomes a day-to-day aspect. There is much potential at the design stage to bring about better risk allocation, incentive compatibility, lower monitoring costs, and transparency and hence reduce the scope for rents. If the prototype of the agreement itself is shoddy then there is the possibility of certain developers using the same to their advantage to create rents. Most power purchase agreements (PPAs) and the IPP framework have been flawed in this sense. Distancing Privatization from Government Privatization is one activity though, where the scope for rents is enormous. Rents could take many forms. Thus delays, interdepartmental wrangling and uncertainties, restrictive presale conditions including insistence upon golden shares can reduce bid values considerably. Then, after sale, if the new owner is able to get rid of government interference, neutralize or do away with the golden share, the rents can be large, though this is not evident. The current low values of the stock of PSUs are in part a result of confusion with regard to disinvestment. If these are corrected after sale, then large value transfers could be said to have taken place even though with reference to the market, these may not translate to abnormal gains for the purchasing party. In the Indian context disinvestment would have to be distanced if not separated from the government. I had argued in (Morris, 2001b) for a constitutional or distanced authority for disinvestment. This is because the credibility of the government (irrespective of which party rules) in carrying out disinvestment in a fair and corruptionfree manner is low if not non-existent. This has happened because of state-failure in India, in many of its efforts to direct economic activity and competitive politics, with one feeding the other. Neither can the route of transparency be an answer, since every aspect of the disinvestment process cannot be disclosed. The disinvestment process does not carry much credibility when it is directed from within the government even if a competent body headed by persons of trusted credentials is undertaking the task. Valuations can always be questioned, and no political party would let an opportunity to question values, go unexploited. A Core within Government The tasks of governance and institutional change as we have outlined above require that at least some section within the government, for some time, is motivated, corruption free, and skillful. Economic reform has the great advatantage that it does not require all of the government to be ‘good’ all the time. That is why reform can be put together from 34 India Infrastructure Report 2002 within the system if adequate pressures to do so exist. Such was the case in the immediate aftermath of the crisis of 1990–1. As such the general ‘impotence of the administrative machinery’, or the ‘system failure’ while real, and a valid explanation for the ineffectiveness of well-meaning officers and politicians18, need not actually stand in the way of reform. The more correct reforms such as direct subsidies, legal changes for BOT type participation, freedom of information laws, growth-oriented macroeconomic policies come into play, the less is the bind of the administration. The growth and development effects of reform would in turn, through larger processes, bring about changes in governance through the system as a whole. For such small groups within the government, regulatory institutions trying to work a new sector development programme, putting together a framework for public– private partnership, writing contracts for the same, or worrying about new frameworks for land acquisition, the key to success would be to accept compromise solutions only when they make sense. Thus whether one chooses cost plus or incentive regulation or ‘created’ markets for electricity generation is not something that is negotiable. The choice should emerge out of the strategy for change for the country as a whole, that is being pursued. If for instance, the strategy is largely one of deregulation, the understanding that ownership changes alone are not adequate ought to follow. Industry structure and the nature of environment for profits is important and the probability of regulatory capture is high. In such a situation then only created markets wherever feasible and incentive regulation elsewhere would be the choice. Cost plus regulation has no place at all. What could possibly be negotiated, is the pace of change towards that new industry structure, and the treatment of ‘stranded assets’. It goes without saying that such key groups and institutions have the right skills and the freedom. One of the challenges today is really to open up administration to lateral entry of experts so that one does not have to wait for the cadres of the bureaucracy to eventually come up with the learning. Lateral recruitment merely in advisory capacity does not help much. Another attribute of success would have to be the originality to contextualize reform to the Indian situation. I had argued for inventive and original solutions (Morris, 2001b). The need to deeply understand our own problems, 18 Some may contest this and claim that ‘system failure’ is an excuse to hide one’s lack of initiative and poor performance. This is no doubt true, but then the implict reference for comparison is that only a very dynamic and politically savvy manager or officer can get things done. Why should the system demand such enterprise out the officer. That only confirms that the system has constraints. It is important to recognize the fact that only great leaders like V. Krishnamurthy could succeed in Indian PSUs is proof of the systemic mess. to contextualize our approach (like deregulation) even if they are derived from elsewhere had been emphasized. No models that worked elsewhere, can on that count alone, be grafted on to the situation here. Experts, including transnational consultants may not have all the answers. (Their answers can in any case be only as good as the background work done by the clients) Thus, there is need to go beyond the beaten circuits. Thus, ‘right-structuring’ the ownership of difficult-to-regulate business like transmission, the need to be particularly bothered about the mode of subsidy administration and, incentive compatibility in proposals for change, to be able to distinguish between political considerations and others that are ‘politicized’ masks for rents, wastage and theft, to recognize the limits of government administration and to be alert enough to take advantage of the few opportunities for political entrepreneurship, are all integral to getting the ‘Second Stage’ of reforms correct. The special characteristics imposed by late-industrialization, low incomes, income inequality, the opportunities in access subsidization, rather than use-subsidization, in postponing regulation when in high growth and expansionary phase of the network, are other sensitivities of successful reformers. CONCLUSION We discussed governance, but argued that the ‘leverage point for change’ to improve governance would generally lie not in attempting improvements in government as a whole, but in policies that engender faster growth and development, in the removal of restrictions, and in correctly deregulating the economy. The basis for the arguments were conceptual, historical and empirical. Today the economy is constrained by conservative monetary (and fiscal) policies and a tame pricing of the Indian rupee. Given the large buffer stocks of food, and the very high responsiveness of exports to the exchange rate there is scope to raise the growth rates substantially. That should be the first task. This point was not argued in this paper but mentioned by reference to my paper on the topic (Morris 1997) which had anticipated the current industrial recession and its nature. Many economists have misunderstood East Asia ‘s success to inter alia lie in laissez faire. This is incorrect. It lies in export-promotion, the simultaneous promotion of both exports and import substitution, possible in a more realistic three commodity model of world trade. The fear of inflation and the fiscal deficit getting out of hand is greatly exaggerated. A longer term strategy for which there may be political difficulties is land reform which has the potential to unlock the constraint of the homemarket for the industrialization of the country. The Challenge to Governance in India The second task is really to right-structure subsidy administration in critical areas: electricity, water, and petroleum sectors where reform is caught in the bind of subsidization. Removal of subsidies would not be the answer since that would require prior reform and would be political hara-kiri. In any case that is not necessary since the true value of subsidies (in terms of actually delivered benefits to the targetted sector) is quite manageable. The replacement of current modes that generate vast rents and create vested interests by direct subsidization is possible. In subsidized groups being able to pay with coupons, developers and providers of the service/product would see uniform prices. Developments in IT, in database management and communication allow the easy identification of citizens for the basis of correct administration of subsidies. The task of coupon distribution given the entitlement and identification is trivial. Even if there are mistakes in identification, they are containable, and can be reduced over a period. Most importantly, mistakes in identification do not affect reform and the management of infrastructural sectors. They can then be reformed quickly. Political support for direct subsidization is likely to be overwhelmingly large, to counter any possible role of vested interests. The need today is to urgently drive towards direct subsidization in electricity, kersosene, irrigation water, fertilizers and chemicals. 35 The third task is more that of governance and institutional development: the economic reforms thus far, have created space for some governance-oriented reform to have an important impact on the economy. If the second task can be simultaneously addressed, then the scope of the changes possible within the government are very large. Once the source of nourishment for corruption can be destroyed, the business of improvements in the performance of government as a whole can be addressed. Even before that, in a more limited way, governance can improve if small groups within government and regulators can take upon themselves the task of doing things the right way: developing drafts for framework legislation like the BOT law, setting up of key organizations like the IDecK or GIDB in Karnataka and Gujarat respectively, developing the right formats for contracting, creating the space for people to directly interact with providers of public services, bringing in markets and commercialization wherever possible, and working towards privatization when state owned enterprises are severely constrained by their dysfunctional interface with government. The need to rightman and professionalize the new bodies including regulatory commissions is obvious. Society has paid too high a price in the poor performance of regulatory institutions set up during the 1990s. REFERENCES 3iNetwork (2001), India Infrastructure Report 2001, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Alam Shehid (1989), Governments and Markets in Economic Development Strategies: Lessons from Korea, Taiwan and Japan, Prager, New York. Amsden, Alice (1989), Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialisation, Oxford University Press, New York. Appu, P.S. (1991), Land Reforms in India: A Survey of Policy, Legislation, and Implementation, Vikas Publications, New Delhi. Bhagwati, Jagdish N. (1970), Indian Planning for Industrialization: Industrialization and Trade Policies Since 1951, Oxford University Press, UK. Bhagwati, Jagdish N. (1982), ‘Directly Unproductive ProfitSeeking (DUP) Activities’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90, 988–1002. Datta–Chaudhury, M. (1981), ‘Industrialisation and Foreign Trade: The Development Experience of South Korea and Philippines’, in Lee, Eddy (ed.) (1981). Dutt, R.C. (1911), The Economic History of India, Volume 1 and 2, republished by Ministry of Information and Broadcasting, Government of India, New Delhi. Gerschenkron, Alexander (1966), ‘Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective’, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Government of Maharashtra (1988), ‘Report of the Commission of Inquiry Regarding Deaths of Patients in JJ Hospital at Bombay in January–February, 1986 Due to Alleged Reaction of Drugs’, headed by Hon. Mr. Justice B. Lentin, Bombay. Gupta, Anita and Sebastian Morris (2001), ‘How Much More of this Infliction? The Cast of Ahmedabad Vadodara Expressway’, in 3iNetwork (2001). Habib, Irfan (1975), ‘Colonisation of the Indian Economy 1754–1900’, Social Scientist, Vol 3, No 8, 23–39. Indian Administrative Reform Commission (1970), ‘The Administrative Reforms Commission and its Work: A Brief Survey’, Manager of Publication, New Delhi. Lall, S. (1994), ‘The East Asian Miracle: Does the Bell Toll for Industrial Strategy? Review of the World Banks’ East Asian Miracle Report’, World Development, Vol. 22, No. 4, 645–54. Leys, Colin (1975), Under Development in Kenya: The Political Economy of Neo-Colonialism, Heineman, London. Lee, Eddy (ed.) (1981), Export-led Industrialisation and Development, International Labour Organisation, Asian Employment Programme. Mamdani, Mehmood (1976), Political Class Formation in Uganda, Heineman, London. Mathur, M.P. (2001), ‘Finances and Functioning of Urban Local Bodies: A Situation Report’, in 3iNetwork (2001). Melekar, Anosh (2000), ‘Mixers and Fixers (Crime) Inside Story of the Rs 1000 Crore Solvent Scam in Gujarat’, The Week, July 16. 36 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Mehta, Abhay (2000), Power Play A Study of the Euron Project, Orient Longman, New Delhi. Morris, S. (1989), ‘The Process of Investment Decisions in the Public Sector: A Study of Delays and Lost Overs’, Institute of Public Enterprise, Mimeo. Morris, S. (1990), ‘Holding Companies, Performance Contracts and Task Orientation in the Public Sector’, Economic and Political Weekly, 6 Nov.–30 Dec., M137–44. Morris, S. (1997), ‘Why not Push for a 9 Per Cent Growth Rate?’, Economic and Political Weekly, 17–24 May, 1153–65. Morris, S., R. Basant, K. Das, K. Ramachandran, and A. Koshy (2001), Growth and Transformation of Small Firms in India, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Morris, Sebastian (2001a), ‘Pioneer Sector Reform and Regulation: The Road Ahead’, in 3iNetwork (2001). Morris, Sebastian (2001b), ‘Issues in Infrastructure Development Today: The Interlinkages’, in 3iNetwork (2001). Nanavaty, Anish (2001), ‘Implications of the 17th Amendment on Water and Wastewater Sector’, in 3iNetwork (2001). Pettigrew, Ardrew M. (1985), The Awakening Giant: Continuity and Change in Imperial Chemical Industries, Blackwell, Oxford. Pundir, B.P. (2000), ‘Vehicular Air Pollution in India: Recent Control Measures and Related Issues’, in 3iNetwork (2001). Sant Girish, Shantanu Dixit, and Subodh Wagle (1995), ‘Dhabol Project PPA: Structure and Eechno-Economic Implications’, Economic and Political Weekly, 17–24 June. Shivji, Issa (1976), Class Strangles in Tanzania, Monthly Review Press, New York. Zhao Dengju (2000), ‘Practices in China for Combating Corruption’, paper presented at the ADB/ OECD Conference on Combating Corruption in the Asia-Pacific Region, Seoul, 11–13 December. The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 3 37 THE INFRASTRUCTURE SECTOR IN INDIA, 2000–1 3.1 A REVIEW OF SECTORS Anupam B. Rastogi In the year 2001, infrastructure sector grew less than expected. There was much discussion about the failures and ‘half achievements’, but there were some successes, too. HIGHLIGHTS The Deepak Parekh Committee Report on Escrow Cover (Government of Karnataka, 2000) unequivocally raised the question of unsustainability of escrow accounts and brought out the importance of privatization of distribution in power sector. One could hardly disagree with the prognosis of Jack Welch that India cannot be a ‘software superpower’ if she does not produce enough power. ‘Everyone thinks the internet shows up here, on the computer, and it doesn’t use power. It’s a wonderful new industry. But the fact is every basis bit of information uses electronics. And if you don’t have power, nothing happen.’ (Singhal et al. 2000). The Enron saga came to full boil and has spurred many tumultuous changes in the sector which will bear fruit in the years to come. Villages continue to suffer incessant power cuts. The failure of the northern grid which plunged a large part of northern India into darkness for a couple of days, brought home the importance of the transmission business. Draft Bill Undoubtedly, the precarious financial health of the state electricity boards (SEBs) can hardly be conducive for any investment. Promoters and investors have shied away from the sector. Policy risks continue to be high. The Electricity Bill drafted by the NCAER (National Council of Applied Economic Research) had gone through eight drafts. The Bill seeks to replace the Indian Electricity Act 1910, the Electricity (Supply) Act 1948 and the Electricity Regulatory Commission Act 1998. The government’s own Draft Bill 2001 is slated to be introduced soon in Parliament. The objective is to bring about comprehensive reforms in the power sector. Whither Convergence The only sector that seems to be attracting private capital is telecommunications, where large projects are being implemented. However, there are problems here, as well. The government continues to drag its feet on the issue of convergence. It has taken too long to draft the convergence bill and its passage. The continuous changes in technology further challenge the boundaries of many departments. This hindered the provision of a legal framework for the development of the telecom sector in India. Industry, however, is going ahead with consolidation through mergers and acquisitions. It is entirely possible that basic operators will formally join hands with cellular operators to fight the government! NHDP Goes Ahead The transportation sector has a few successes in its bag and a few failures too. Ports witnessed the beginnings of corporatization and serious efforts at privatization of portrelated services. In Roads, the National Highways Development Plan (NHDP) is progressing on schedule and many states are spending fair sums of money to improve their state highways and district roads. But the battle against ‘short-termism’ 38 India Infrastructure Report 2002 needs to continue. The focus is on construction rather than providing good road service to people on a sustainable basis. Cratered surfaces of newly refurbished roads and highways are expensive witnesses of this folly. The government has further emphatically reiterated that road building in rural India would be a fully sponsored by the Central government. However, there are no visible developments on the ground. Cross nodal connectivity is the new mantra, but other than the Planning Commission’s Draft Integrated Transport Policy (GOI, 2000b), there is no big blue print to make it happen. Railways and NHAI The much awaited Rakesh Mohan Committee Report on Railways (GOI, 2001d) was submitted to the Railway Minister. The major reorganization of the Railways suggested in the report is being studied by an internal committee of the Railways! Severely strapped for resources, the Railways have started courting state governments and private sector organizations to get resources for developing interconnectivity with ports and other bulk cargo facilities. The NHAI (National Highways Authority of India) too has a ground plan ready to connect major ports with the Golden Quadrilateral. Some Southern Cities Move Ahead Urban infrastructure remained in doldrums. But there is much talk about providing better services—drinking water, sewerage system, district roads—in cities. Finances of urban local bodies have been stretched to their limits and user charges are so low that they cannot even support operation and maintenance costs of these services. However, some metropolitan cities such as Bangalore, Chennai and Hyderabad, have taken certain steps in the right direction. Some states such as Haryana and Uttar Pradesh have been encouraging the private sector in providing civic services in ‘new’ cities such as Gurgaon and the NOIDA area. Rajasthan has introduced a comprehensive bill which aims to promote private-public partnership in providing many civic amenities in all its cities. Much has occurred in the approach of most state governments. The competition to attract private capital to provide all types of economic infrastructure is discernible. However, the bureaucracy in many ways continues to be suspicious of the ‘profit motive’ and finds it difficult to accept that there are risks involved in private provision of services, which need to priced. Investments in Infrastructure Reflecting the general slowdown in the economy, the infrastructure index of the Ministry of Industry and Commerce registered a dismal one per cent growth during April-June 2001, compared to 9.3 per cent during the corresponding period of the previous year. The growth rate of infrastructure-related industries—electricity, coal, steel, crude petroleum, petroleum refinery products, and cement— accounting for a weight of 26.68 per cent in the index of industrial production (IIP), was much lower at 5.3 per cent during 2001–1 compared to 9.1 per cent in the previous year. The slowdown was particularly pronounced for electricity, steel and cement, reflecting basically the paucity of investment demand. Obviously the severe recession in the industrial sector has had its effect on the infrastructure sector. The cumulative industrial growth for July 2000 to June 2001 was also much lower at 1.5 per cent against 5.9 per cent in the previous period. Sanctions and Disbursement The sluggishness in investment demand from the private sector is reflected in the performance of domestic financial institutions (DFIs) in a major way. The total sanctions of the three top ranking DFIs—IDBI, ICICI and IDFC— grew only at a rate of 21 per cent during 2000–1 as against a robust 44 per cent last year. More disturbingly, the total disbursements of the three DFIs had slided to 15 per cent growth compared to 42 per cent growth during the previous year. Power and Telecom continued to rely on traditional project financing methods. The Transport sector witnessed new Table 3.1.1 Sanctions and Disbursement of Major DFIs (in Rs. crore) Disbursements 1998–9 IDFC ICICI IDBI Total Percentage growth over previous year 374 15807 14470 30651 1999–2000 642 25092 17059 43537 42 Sanctions 2000–1 1998–9 1999–2000 2000–1 762 31965 17500 50225 15 1682 24717 23745 50144 1866 43523 26966 72349 44 2467 56092 28711 87270 21 The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 initiatives. Work on the Golden Quadrilateral is almost on schedule. Success achieved in execution of the Moradabadby-pass using an SPV (special purpose vehicle) has emboldened NHAI to try some more projects using the same method. It was rail-port interconnectivity that saw long-term concession awarded to the private sector by the Railways. The Railways would construct the fixed infrastructure and maintain and operate it, the private sector would assure a certain fixed amount of traffic and raise funds to build the facilities. The urban infrastructure witnessed the use of many forms of financial initiatives. Despite all the jugglery, if the urban bodies cannot pay, these initiatives are likely to remain non-starters. Fiscal Incentives for Infrastructure: The Union Budget of 2001–2 proposed certain measures to provide a boost to infrastructure investments and industrial growth. But the decision-making process and governance of the country came to a standstill because of the series of unexpected political developments. PM’s Task Force on Infrastructure: This Committee after designing detailed framework and implementation of the NHDP and the North-South and East-West corridors considered issues related to ports, aviation and integrated transport policy. PM’s Economic Advisory Council: It was probably the first time that the report of the Council was forthright in detailing all that ails in the sector. It pointed out that inadequate user charges (and the states’ inability to compensate the private sector), and regulatory uncertainty, are the two main causes for the poor response of the private sector’s participation in the sector. There are enormous risks in the current scenario which have held back the private sector from enthusiastic participation. The main recommendations of the Council are delineated in Box 3.1.1. INITIATIVES AT THE STATE LEVEL 39 operation and maintenance of infrastructure projects. The basic reason for this is that contracts can be specified, and the profit motive used to create incentives for its delivery. The government is preparing a comprehensive legislation for reducing administrative and procedural delays, identifying generic project risks, detailing various incentives, detailing the project delivery process and procedures for reconciliation of disputes. Andhra Pradesh The state enacted the Infrastructure Development Enabling Act 2001 (Draft Bill) to provide for the rapid development of physical and social infrastructure in the state and to attract private sector participation. The bill provides comprehensive legislation. It also lays down procedures for reconciliation of disputes and provides for other ancillary and incidental matters with a view to present bankable projects to the private sector and improve the level of infrastructure in the state. Rajasthan To attract private investment in urban infrastructure, Rajasthan is introducing freer, market-friendly policies and legislations. Policy changes and legislative amendments include the New Rajasthan Town and Country Planning Act, nearly three hundred amendments to the Rajasthan Municipal Act 1959, abolition of the Urban Land Ceiling and Regulation Act, and amendments to the Rajasthan Urban Improvement Act 1959, Jaipur Development Act 1982 and Urban Land Allotment Rules 1974. Rajasthan is the third state, after Haryana and Uttar Pradesh to invite private sector to liberally invest in joint sector townships on BOT basis. While the latter offered townships (such as Gurgaon, Greater NOIDA) on standalone basis, Rajasthan is offering majority of its urban centres to prospective developers. West Bengal POWER The West Bengal government is in the process of framing a policy for allowing private participation in infrastructure like roads, flyovers and water distribution. The policy is going to be introduced through a government resolution rather than through legislation—a weak initiative since the government of the day can change the rule of the game later. Private parties will be allowed to exploit adjoining lands for commercial exploitation. Open bidding is to be the basis of private participation. True reform is awaited in the power sector. The single buyer model of private generation of electricity could never have taken off with the SEBs in near bankrupt conditions. The process was started with the Deepak Parekh Committee Report which questioned the suitability of escrow account of SEB receivable and escrow capacity of KSEB (Karnataka State Electricity Board). The Committee also suggested that funding should be done on the strength and viability of the project itself. Important suggestions were made in the expert group reports (GOI, 2001a and 2001b), the energy review committee reports (GOM, 2001a and 2001b) popularly known as the Godbole Committee Report. Finally, the Electricity Act 2001 is ready. If passed by Parliament and implemented, it will be Karnataka The government has recognized the importance of private sector participation in the designing, financing, construction, AND ENERGY 40 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 3.1.1 Infrastructure Sector in the Report of the PM’s Economic Advisory Council The council’s report on economy laid emphasis on investments in economic infrastructure if India is to achieve a growth target of 8 per cent during the Tenth Five Year Plan. Private sector investments were muted because the pre-conditions for successful large scale entry of the private sector were not yet met. Two main reasons provided in the report were inadequate user charges and regulatory uncertainty. While infrastructure remains an exclusive public sector monopoly, the rationalization of user charges in infrastructure is abso lutely vital. A regulatory regime that is seen to be fair to consumers and also sensitive to the legitimate needs of investors, is abs olutely essential. POWER ‘The flaw in the policy with regard to electricity was the failure to recognize that the root of the problem lies in the financial unviability of the state electricity boards. This has made independent power projects (IPPs) look for temporary solutions such as escrow arrangements and central government guarantees which simply do not address the core problem.’ It suggested that the huge transmission and distribution losses could be brought down through privatization of distribution as the privatized areas would help achieve better efficiency from the distribution system. The central government should play a pivotal role in the reform of SEBs (State Electricity Boards) as large parts of these dues are to the central government organizations, such as NTPC, Coal India, Railways, and NHPC. In view of the rapid convergence of telecom, IT and media, a new comprehensive statute, which creates the framework of single license for multiple services, needs to replace the Indian Telegraph Act of 1885. The government must levy fees to meet administration and regulatory costs, along with universal service obligation charges, through revenue sharing, and not as an avenue to raise resources for the government. Increasing competition within the sector will ensure benefits of reduction in license fees is passed on to consumers. The only area where government should collect rent is in the allocation of spectrum, which is a scarce resource. ROADS The council suggested that the private sector be encouraged to participate in road projects through the BOT (build, operate, transfer)/ Annuity system as ‘EPC (engineering, procurement and construction), and O&M (operations and maintenance) contracts be merged and given to the same contractor who would be responsible for construction and maintenance of the road during the concession period. According to the committee, private sector made little progress for so long because the government found it more attractive to raise money cheaply through riskless gilt-edged debt, rather than paying the private sector’s capital costs with their risk-premium. PORTS The existing port trusts should be corporatized and turned into landlord ports that would then invite different operators, both public and private, to invest in cargo handling and port infrastructure services. The ports as such should concentrate on the development of common user general cargo facilities. Rather than fresh ports it suggested existing ports be optimally utilized through efficiency enhancing investments. Tariff fixing is no longer necessary as intra-port and inter-port competition will ensure competitive pricing of services. RAILWAYS The council strongly recommended depoliticization of Railways, rationalization of user charges and corporatization of production units. Railways have a key role in initiating development of the key inter- and trans-modal facilities. CIVIL AVIATION The council recommended leasing the major airports (Delhi, Mumbai, Chennai and Calcutta), and inviting private sector management of airports. An independent regulatory framework for ensuring economic regulation in the sector was suggested as there are many operators. The inland air travel tax and foreign travel tax should be converted into a common ‘civil aviation cess’ to ensure sufficient flow of funds to develop civil aviation facilities in other parts of the country. the harbinger of a new market structure for the power sector in the country (see a review of the Draft Bill 2001 in Section 10.3). Little progress has been made in bringing new investment to the power sector. During the past year no major IPP has achieved financial closure. The main reason for this is the The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 non-resolution of a bankable security package for lenders; finalization of the escrow agreement and its operationalization1. The power ministry has firmed up an action plan to double the electricity generation capacity in the country to over 2 lakh MW by the end of the Eleventh Five Year Plan (2008–12). Projects aggregating 1,07,000 MW generation capacity had been identified by the ministry for completion during the Tenth and the Eleventh Five Year Plans. While 43,000 MW additional power generation capacity has been planned for the Tenth Plan, 64,000 MW target has been fixed for the Eleventh Plan. The institutional and policy changes to realize even half of these are challenging. We are doubtful, about the achievement of these targets, but need not presume failure that would be inevitable. Under the action plan, the power ministry has envisaged large-sized thermal units such as 3 × 660 MW Sipat (NTPC) and 6 × 660 Hirma (IPP) to reap economies of scale. The Plan would target 35,000 MW additional generation capacity in the hydel sector as against the existing capacity of 25,000 MW! The likely problems in land acquisition and in management of environmental problems, and rehabilitation and resettlement, do not find adequate mention. Under the Tenth Five Year Plan, the Power Ministry hopes to operationalize the mega power policy with a set of fiscal and other incentives (such as customs duty exemption and ten year tax holiday) extended to large-sized inter-state projects of over 1,000 MW for thermal, and 750 MW for hydro. The ministry hopes that these steps would ensure offtake of power from identified mega projects to beneficiary states and bulk consumers on the basis of long-term power purchase agreements. It has proposed a five-point strategy to convert lossmaking SEBs into viable profit-making concerns. The strategy was chalked out after taking into account the recommendations of the Ahluwalia Committee (GOI 2001b), established to suggest remedial measures on sick power utilities. The strategy includes working out statespecific revival packages as part of the SEBs’ restructuring exercise, preparation of district-wise distribution plan across the country, converting all distribution feeders into proper profit-centres, ensuring metering of all consumer connections, and bringing the accounting procedures of all SEBs in line with the international standards for greater transparency2. 1 [To continue viewing the problems of the power sector as arising out of escrow is itself a fallacy. The source of disease is thereby not addressed (see Chapter 2).] 2 These are really operational decisions of any electricity company. That at a policy level the government has to lay down 100 per cent metering is indicative of the deepseated problems to SEBs, wherein, even operational decisions have to be taken by the government. 41 Settlement of SEB Dues The chief ministers’ conference, held on 3 March 2001 under the chairmanship of the Prime Minister deliberated on the Power sector. They agreed to meet the challenge of restructuring head-on. The Union Minister of Power constituted an expert group under the chairmanship of Montek Singh Ahluwalia to recommend measures for onetime settlement of outstanding dues of SEBs to the central public sector undertaking (CPSUs) and the dues from CPSUs to SEBs. The group was also entrusted to suggest a strategy for capital restructuring of SEBs to make them operationally viable. The expert group’s recommendation includes a package of incentives and disincentives linked to commercial discipline and initiation of a process of reforms. The group emphasized that the recommendations have to be accepted in toto. For the states participating in the scheme, the group recommended 50 percent waiver of the surcharge/interest on delayed payments. The rest of the dues, including the full principal payment amounting to Rs 33,600 crore was to be securitized through tax-free bonds bearing an interest rate of 8.5 per cent and issued by the respective state governments. The group recommended that if a state defaults in current payments for power/fuel, there should be a graded reduction in the supply of power from central power stations and coal supplies to the state. Further, SEBs should accept reform-based performance milestones such as setting up of SERCs (State Electricity Regulatory Commissions), metering of distribution feeders and improvement in revenue realization. Several states including MP, Orissa and West Bengal have objected to the severe penalties proposed by the panel against defaults. The government has accepted the first part of the report. SEB Restructuring In the second part of the report (GOI, 2001b), the group has proposed a comprehensive restructuring of the sector to make it viable. The causes of failures are in line with other reports. The committee has suggested that market borrowings and private investments should be tapped to finance expansion and modernization plans in the sector. It has also recommended waiver of loans provided by the states to the SEBs and central assistance for bridging the revenue gap, meeting the costs of the work force rationalization and adjustment costs for shifting to open access. The group has recommended that the adjustment costs of the transition would have to be funded out of the budgetary support. Further, it has recommended central assistance equal to 5 per cent of the total sale revenue of an SEB in 2000–1, subject to a ceiling of Rs 100 crore per year for allowing ‘open access’ of electricity. It has also suggested that the 42 India Infrastructure Report 2002 assistance should be provided to the SEB or its successor entities for a period of three years after ‘open access’ is guaranteed. The group has recommended that during the first year of direct sale by any private generator to bulk consumers, the SEB or the transmission company should receive central assistance of 50 paise per unit of power wheeled, subject to a ceiling of Rs 250 crore. The panel has recommended that ‘this assistance should be reduced to 25 paise per unit during the second and third years, the ceiling remaining unchanged’. It has estimated that the central assistance on this count would not exceed Rs 10,000 crore during the Tenth Plan. The second part of the report has not yet been accepted by the government. The Electricity Bill 20013 The salient features of the bill are: • No techno-economic clearance for generating stations and no state licencing • Non-discriminatory and open access to the transmission system • Major role for the regulators, SERCs and CERC (Central Electricity Regulatory Commission) in licencing, tariff, grid rules, and access rules • Provides for power trading, and the eventual creation of a spot market • Graduated reduction of subsidies; and • Mandate for the regulator to cover tariff in all segments. DPC Report4 The Energy Review Committee headed by Madhav Godbole found a complete failure of governance of various governments at the state as well as the central government level in their dealings with DPC (GOM, 2001a). In the report (part I) the committee found that the Enron power purchase agreement (PPA) had built in excessive payments to Enron from the Maharashtra State Electricity Board (MSEB) as a result of undue burden of the regasification facility, high recovery charges of shipping and harbour and O&M, and inflated claims of fuel consumption. Based on these findings the committee recommended a reduction in tariff. The committee drew up a blueprint for restructuring the Maharashtra State Electricity Board (MSEB). The committee emphasized two elements essential to the success of the reforms: a reliable estimate of how much power is consumed by each user group; and an organizational structure, which devolves the responsibility to measure consumption and 3 See a critical review of the Bill in Section 9.4. 4 Section 6.6 draws the governance implications from the findings of the Godbole Committee Report. collect charges to entities as close as possible to each user group possible. It has suggested trifurcation of the MSEB. There is to be a set of independent generation companies formed by clubbing the existing facilities into sets of six. Some are to be open to privatization, others not. Likewise, there will be a set of independent distribution companies which may be offered for private ownership. In keeping with the natural monopoly characteristics of this activity, the transmission company will continue to be under a single operator. The company will be kept under public ownership, with wheeling charges to be determined by the state’s power regulator. Over time, it may be handed over to a private operator, but private ownership of the transmission company is not envisaged by the report. The committee has rationalized that the overriding aim of power sector reforms is getting people to pay for the power they use at the rates which are set for that particular category. If the provision of power at below cost to specific categories of users, for example farmers, is deemed socially desirable, then it is incumbent on the government to reimburse the distribution company the difference between the price charged and the cost incurred. So far, this subsidization has been done by underwriting the losses of the SEBs, but under the reform blueprint, it now needs to be done by an overt transfer from the government to the private distributor who will then buy power at the regulated rate from the generators5. For the system as a whole to be viable, the distributor needs to know precisely who is to be thus favoured and how much this group collectively consumes. Without an accurate estimate of consumption, rates cannot be set with any degree of precision. Distribution companies making plans based on erroneous estimates of paid-for consumption run grave risks of financial nonviability. Interestingly, the committee has recommended that the proceeds of privatization be deposited in the Power Sector Reform Fund, a state level fund. According to the report, ‘the essential feature of the model (defined as the Maharashtra model) is to avoid the problems of persisting with government ownership, mixed zones, the single buyer approach and an annual regulatory process, while at the same time phasing in the transition to a full-fledged market system, as envisaged in the proposed Electricity Bill, in an orderly manner’. (GOM 2001b, p. 88) POWER SECTOR REFORMS AND STATES Reforms at the state level have been moving slowly. Administrative changes have not been easy to bring about. 5 Even this would not work, since the incentives to over report consumption by the subsidized sector would remain. Only direct subsidization would work. See Chapter 1. The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 43 Table 3.1.2 Power Sector ‘Reforms’: A ‘Score Card’ for Statesa Parameter SEB Restructuring Constitution of SERC Andhra Pradesh ü ü Assam Bihar Chattisgarh Delhi Goa Gujarat Haryana Himachal Pradesh J&K Jharkhand Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh Uttaranchal West Bengal North East States Commercialization of Distribution MoU with Central Government Strategy being finalized – – – – – – – – – ü ü Committed—proposal to be done during 2001 – – – Reform law approved ü Strategy being by GOI finalized ü ü Strategy being finalized – ü – – – – – – – ü * To be completed by Dec 2002 The state has proposed to reorganize SEB into three profit centres Reform Law passed ü – in the Assembly – ü ü ü ü ü – Notified; yet to – be constituted ü ü Committed – ü – ü ü Strategy being finalized – – – – ü ü Willing to constitute joint Electricity Regulatory Commission – – – – – – ü ü – – – * ü – – – – – ü – – a These constitute reforms in a formal sense. In content restructuring is not uniform across SEBs. Gujarat has trifurcated on paper, the GEB, purely to meet certain targets set by the ADB (Asian Development Bank) while the sector continues as before. It is hoped that the Reform Law would make a difference. Source: CII (2001), Press Release. Some state regulatory authorities have also passed tariff orders but restructuring and corporatization of the SEBs is proving difficult. Internal changes due to corporatization has been even more difficult. Table 3.1.2 succinctly captures the progress of reforms in various states. Karnataka The expansion of the generation capacity at the Raichur Thermal Power Station (RTPS, Unit 7) by the Karnataka Power Corporation Limited (KPCL) became the first project where financial closure is subject to reforms. The government of Karnataka, KPCL, Karnataka Power Transmission Corporation Limited (KPTCL) and IDFC signed a multipartite agreement which specifies milestones for reforms to be met by the state government and KPTCL such as privatization of distribution within a specified period, commitment to financial discipline and creation of a dedicated power fund. Encouraged by this development, the Union Finance Minister has suggested a conditional lending programme for IPPs by financial institutions, in line with the multipartite agreement in Karnataka, as an alternative to escrow based lending. Orissa Power sector reforms initiated in Orissa six years ago have come to a halt (a detailed analysis is given in Section 9.3). AES Corporation, the US power major has a 49 per cent stake in the Orissa Power Generation Company (OPGC) 44 India Infrastructure Report 2002 and a 51 per cent stake in Central Electricity Supply Company (CESCO), distribution company for central Orissa. The AES has initiated arbitration proceedings against GRIDCO for non-payment of dues and has threatened to pull out of CESCO if tariffs are not increased. CESCO is losing several crores every month in high costs and low tariffs. The power corporation is in red after six years of operation. The public, too, is not appreciative of slow and halting manner of the reforms process. From being a model in power sector reforms, Orissa’s experience is now a lesson on how not to go about privatizing the power sector. Andhra Pradesh Andhra Pradesh (AP) has provided major boost to the power sector reforms. The Rural Electrification Corporation (REC) has almost doubled the disbursement amount to the state to undertake rural electrification programmes last year. Under its lending programme for AP, the corporation has decided to disburse Rs 800 crore to the Transmission Corporation of Andhra Pradesh (APTransco) in 2001, which is substantially higher than Rs 420 crore during the previous year. Rajasthan The Rajasthan government has decided to spend Rs 2,000 crore on power sector reforms in the next two years in an attempt to make the energy sector self-reliant by 2005. Jhunjhunu, Jodhpur, Alwar and Jalore districts of the state have been identified under the Accelerated Power Development Project of the central government. Rajasthan, facing power shortage, has decided to work more on non-conventional resources like solar and wind energy. The first wind power project has been set up by an IPP in the border district of Jaisalmer. The state has already achieved a record by setting up 9,900 domestic light connections based on solar energy. According to the Renewable Energy Development Authority (REDA), three demonstration wind power stations are already functioning in Jaisalmer, Phalodi and Devgarh. All the three wind units have generated more than 7 million units of electricity so far. Jharkhand Recognizing the need to open up the power sector to private investment, Jharkhand has decided to privatize electricity supply in the state. Power supply as well as revenue collection will be first privatized in the state capital, Ranchi, on an experimental basis. If successful, it will be implemented in Jamshedpur, Bokaro, Dhanbad and other towns. Delhi The Delhi Vidyut Board (DVB) has invited financial bids for privatization of three distribution companies. The Board has received bids for divesting 51 per cent stake from private companies and final financial bids are to be called soon. Under the scheme, the balance 49 per cent would be held by the government but the strategic partner would be given complete freedom in running the distribution companies. Tamil Nadu US based power major CMS Energy has threatened to pull out of the US $ 1.4 billion Ennore power project if the Union government does not agree to provide a counter guarantee on payments. The state government has strongly advised the Centre not to agree to a counter guarantee. The corporation has demanded that the government modify the payment security mechanisms for the Ennore project. CMS Energy holds 26 per cent of the equity in Dakshin Bharat Energy Consortium (DBEC), which is executing the 1,850 MW project. The central government is working to provide a type of counter guarantee under a new terminology called ‘termination guarantee’. Serious doubts are being raised as to whether the multi-million dollar integrated liquefied natural gas (LNG) import terminal-cum-power project proposed in Tamil Nadu will take off. The DBEC was willing to sell the entire power generated from the Ennore project to the PTC. Tamil Nadu Electricity Board (TNEB), however, decided that it will buy only 750 MW of power on long-term basis. The MoU stipulates this and states that PTC will buy the power generated from Ennore as per the PPA terms agreed to between PTC and the developer, namely, DBEC and in consultation between TNEB and other beneficiary states. The company has drawn the Prime Minister’s attention to the signing of the Joint Development Agreement on 14 September 2000 in Washington, giving the Ennore project special status by both the American and Indian governments. The agreement sought completion of the Payment Security Mechanism (PSM) concept by 15 December and full PSM documentation by 31 March 2000. The government is targeting to generate 10 per cent of the power requirement from renewable energy sources and plans to set up additional generation capacity of 10,000 MW and a target for electrifying 18,000 remote unelectrified villages by 2012. Andhra Pradesh leads in power generation from bio-mass such as bagasse, rice husk and agricultural waste. Fifty plants of 6 MW range each had been sanctioned, of which five had been commissioned and 25 had been sanctioned loans. All the plants are expected to be fully operational in two years, accounting for a total of 300 MW of additional power. Private entrepreneurs now produce wind electricity in nine states. Together, they have a total installed capacity of over 1100 MW — Karnataka has 40 MW, Andhra Pradesh The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 over 90 MW and Tamil Nadu over 800 MW. During the 2000–1 fiscal year, the 40 MW installed capacity in the state produced 71.1 MW electricity, 8 per cent of the 882.6 million units from renewables sources (solar, bi-product steam from sugar companies, biomass and small hydel). OTHER SECTORS Upstream Hydrocarbon Regulatory Authority The Union government has almost reached a consensus to constitute a separate regulatory authority for the upstream hydrocarbon sector. This has become all the more important in view of the recent round of bidding under the new exploration licencing policy. The upstream hydrocarbon regulatory authority (UHRA) would be set up once the operational framework is finalized. A bill to this effect is expected to be introduced in Parliament. It is mooted that UHRA should not be subservient to the government in its daily functioning and that government interference should be minimal, along the same lines as the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI). UHRA should have full operational and functional autonomy within a framework of set rules and regulations laid down by the government. Public overseeing of the institution could be ensured through annual review by the government and auditing by CAG (Comptroller and Auditor General of India). Roads Besides telecom, construction activity of arterial roads has been the most visible sign of the ‘new’ infrastructure. The road widening (four lane) projects on the Golden Quadrilateral are being expeditiously implemented by NHAI with funds being raised from a variety of sources—budgetary resources, multi lateral borrowings (World Bank/ADB), market borrowings by NHAI and private participation. The first major BOT project on national highways using the annuity approach, four laning of the Panagarh Palsit stretch on NH 2 received better response. Six other four laning projects have been offered to the private sector on the annuity format. Several applicants have qualified to bid for these projects. IDFC has been involved in this initiative as an advisor to NHAI from the onset, defining the concept, finalization of the evaluation parameters for qualification and final selection, procuring documentation, managing the procurement process, finalizing the BOT concession structure and concession agreement, and negotiating with bidders. The first major BOT project on National Highways using direct tolling approach—six laning of the Jaipur Kisangarh stretch on NH 8 received poor response with 45 only one bid. Moradabad bypass, implemented by a whollyowned subsidiary of NHAI, started functioning in 2001. The recently commissioned first phase of the Moradabad bypass has received enthusiastic response from users, with toll collections over Rs 1 lakh per day in less than a month since the road was opened to the public. A few more BOT projects which became operational during the year were the Delhi-NOIDA toll bridge, Wainganga bridge project near Nagpur, and Baroda-Halol four laning project. Several state governments, such as Maharashtra, Karnataka, Kerala and Punjab, are pursuing initiatives for road development, some of them through dedicated road development or infrastructure development corporations. Motorists will now have to pay for driving on newlyupgraded Indian highways. The government plans to toll the entire NHDP in perpetuity. This means that BOT roads are likely to be tolled even after the end of the concession period. The government has fixed a rate of 40 paise per kilometer for cars and an upper limit of Rs 1.40 for heavy vehicles. NHAI is to finalize the toll for different stretches, including bridges. It is estimated that NHAI will mop up annual revenues worth Rs 20 lakh per km through tolling of every completed kilometre of highway along the Golden Quadrilateral linking the four metros of Delhi, Mumbai, Kolkata and Chennai. Taking into account a construction cost of Rs 4 crore per km, this works out to an average recovery of about 5 per cent of the total funds invested for developing the Golden Quadrilateral. The SPV route appears to be the new buzzword fuelling India’s great highway dream. This new financing route is fast catching the fancy of the NHAI. The authority is considering the option of taking up projects through the SPV route on the Ahmedabad-Vadodara Expressway and plans to connect 12 ports including Kandla, Cochin, Paradip, Tuticorin, Haldia, JNPT, Vizag and Marmugao. In future SPV projects, NHAI proposes to invest 30 per cent of the equity of the project with the EPC contractor contributing a minor 5– 10 per cent so that there is a sense of ownership towards the project. However, the success of the SPV route, would depend upon identification of commercially viable projects. NHAI hopes to take up projects worth Rs 2,500 crore via the SPV route. The Central Road Fund It is hoped that the Central Road Fund will ensure funds raised through the cess will be used for road development. The act, however, does not provide for complete ring fencing of the cess fund. Establishment of a road board to manage funds professionally is not mandatory in the act. The government has lost the opportunity to ensure that ‘users’ get the quality of roads they pay for. A critical assessment of the act is given in Box 3.1.2. 46 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 3.1.2 The Central Road Fund The Central Road Fund Act 2000 gives statutory power to establish a Central Road Fund for development and maintenance of national highways and state roads, development of rural roads, construction of under- or over-head railway bridges, erection of safety works at unmanned rail-road crossings and other prescribed. The cess on petrol and high-speed diesel (HSD) will be levied and collected at the rate of rupee one per litre. The proceeds of the cess shall first be credited to the Consolidated Fund of India; the central government may credit proceeds to the fund e xtend grants and loans. Any fund provided by the central government for the development and maintenance of state roads is also to be credited to the fund. The balance to the credit of the fund is not to lapse at the end of the financial year. The fund is to be administered by the central government and is to allocate and disburse money to concerned departments. Projects of state roads, approved by the central government using set criteria to be financed out of the share for state roads shall be monitored by the central government. Fifty per cent of the cess on HSD is to be allocated for the development of rural roadsand the balance as follows: 7.5 per cent shall go for the development and maintenance of national highways; 12.5 per cent for the construction of under- or over-head railway bridges; 27 per cent on development and maintenance of state roads; and 3 per cent on central government approved speci fic state road projects. The salient features of the Act are: • • from • • • Cess collected from users shall be spent on development and maintenance of roads. All the central government funds earmarked for road sector shall be channelized through the fund. State road projects financed the fund shall follow established criteria. Regulation and control of motor vehicles throughout the country come within the jurisdiction of the central government. There is no provision for a cess drawback for off-road usage of HSD which will keep the administration of the fund simple. Money from the fund cannot be allocated for the maintenance of an expressway. CRITICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE ACT • The administration of the fund remains with the central government and there is no statutory provision for an oversight board having user groups representation. • The proceeds of the cess are not completely ring-fenced; the central government is required to credit the proceeds to the fund from time to time after deducting the expenses of collection. • The fund has no budget constraint as the government may credit money by way of grants or loans. The government has powers to disburse funds to any prescribed project. • The fund remains under political control except that proportion of money to be spent on development and maintenance of national highways is fixed. • The act provides a weak legal basis to the fund but it will have published financial rules and regulations. The fund shall not be subject to independent, technical and financial audits. Annuity vs EPC In public-private partnership for infrastructure financing, received wisdom is that the contract should be such that risk ought to be borne by the party that is best able to mitigate it. Annuity is one such instrument. Soon after NHAI received the bid for the first annuity project, it received extremely sharp criticism from financial circles and analysts. Criticism of the popular press was based on prices quoted by the Gaumuda–WCT combine of Malaysia for Rs 69.8 crore (half yearly payments) for the PanagarhPalsit pilot project. This was for a stretch of only 65 kms. They compared the annuity to the cost of four-laning a two lane highway at approximately Rs 4 crore per kilometer. However, one needs to consider the price to be paid for implementing a pilot project. It was expected that the prices would be lower once private entrepreneurs gain confidence in the concept. The annuity method is considered the most risk-free variant of BOT highway projects with private sector participation. However, analysts objected to annuity concept on the following grounds (Haldia, 2000): • Annuity payments essentially entail budgetary funding on a deferred basis. Tight budget constraint, implies that only a fraction of the development programme can be sustained. • Price at which a private company can raise funds from the market will be higher than that of the government. • Dichotomy arises when user pays toll only on some roads. Political justification for a toll road at one place and annuity payment at another place will be difficult to sustain. • To support annuity payments by the state government for state roads, it is not easy to impose another cess to support a state road fund. The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 • The developer demands a traffic guarantee or even a revenue guarantee which goes against the philosophy of private enterprise6. The annuity programme is a logical way of getting better management control into the public sector. The government still manages virtually the entire road sector and has the option to collect toll on these roads7. Subsequent bids for annuity based projects have countered criticism from the popular press. The annuity prices quoted by the Hyderabad based G. Mallikarjun Rao (GMR) group for three projects has again suggested that this is a viable alternative. The GMR group has quoted Rs 29.48 crore for the Tuni-Ankapalle project, Rs 37.59 crore for the Dharwad-Belgaum project and Rs 41.85 crore for the Tindivanam-Tambaram project. The internal rate of return (IRR) works out at about seven per cent. In conclusion, whereas the BOT route tilts the burden of project risks and responsibilities towards the private developer, the annuity route provides for a more balanced approach to risk and responsibility allocation between the project participants. The government has been able to strike the right balance so far by adopting the annuity scheme on seven stretches totaling nearly 450 kms. Toll Roads The first BOT project (Rs 673 crore six lane highway project between Jaipur and Kishangarh on NH 8 in Rajasthan) under the direct tolling method is likely to be awarded to Larsen & Toubro and Joannou & Paraskevaides (Overseas) Ltd of Cyprus. The bare construction cost of the project is estimated at around Rs 493 crores. However, the total project cost is expected to rise to Rs 673 crore after factoring interest during construction (IDC). The successful bidder will develop the highway and recover costs by collecting tolls from the users directly during a concession period spanning 15 years. The agreement provides for a 100 per cent indexation to the wholesale price index (WPI) while revising the toll fees annually. Accordingly, increase in inflation will be passed on to the users fully at the time of annual revision in toll. Rural Roads The Pradhanmantri Gram Sadak Yojna was launched in August 2000. The Prime Minister has reiterated the government’s commitment to this programme. The scheme, 6 For the argument that the larger gains from involving the private sector are in allocative efficiency, see section 6.1. 7 Annuities though may not lead to better allocative efficiency, because governments still decide the road location. They still do have the benefit of private construction, maintenance and management. 47 expected to connect 1.4 lakh habitations with the highway network, has a total outlay of Rs 58,200 crore over the seven year period. Approval from the Planning Commission has been waived for this scheme. The programme would be fully funded by the Centre on the basis of state government project reports. Under the programme, unconnected habitations in rural areas with a population of 1,000 or more is planned to be connected with all-weather roads in three years. In the second stage all habitations with a population of over 500 persons are to be covered by the end of Tenth Plan. The third stage extends to northern-eastern states, Sikkim, Himachal Pradesh, Jammu and Kashmir, Uttaranchal and the desert areas. The objective is to connect habitations with a population of 250 persons and above. The roads constructed under this programme would be maintained by panchayati raj institutions. The ministry of rural development will be the nodal implementation agency to raise additional financial resources from the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank to complete the programme by 2007. The ministry of rural development has been asked to set up a Rural Road Development Agency to provide advice on technical, quality control, and management aspects of the projects. The present source of funds comes from the 50 per cent share of cess on highspeed diesel totaling over Rs 17,500 crores during the sevenyear period. Ports Following the issue of guidelines in June 1988 for the formation of joint ventures by major ports with foreign ports, minor ports and private operators, necessary amendments to the Major Port Trusts Act 1963 have been effected and enforced. The government has also decided to initiate the process of phased corporatization of major ports to enable them to operate in a market-oriented economy with adequate flexibility. Steps have been initiated for the corporatization of the Jawaharlal Nehru Port at Navi Mumbai, New Mangalore Port, Mormugao Port and Tuticorin Port. The government has also planned to develop hub ports, one in the east at Chennai Port and one on the west coast at Navi Mumbai. With the globalization of the Indian economy, creation and upgradation of port and shipping services to international standards is essential. By allowing joint ventures, the government intends to attract new technology, introduce better managerial practices, expedite implementation of schemes and foster strategic alliances with minor ports. The Peninsular and Oriental (P&O) Steam Navigation Ltd of Australia has taken over the Rs 400 crore container terminal project at Chennai port. P&O was selected as the preferred bidder in 2000, but took control of the facility 48 India Infrastructure Report 2002 only in 2001. The terminal will be constructed on BOT basis. The mandate includes developing and managing the terminal for a 30-year period, with construction scheduled to be completed in two years. P&O Ports anticipates investments to the tune of $130 million in the first five years of the concession period for promoting Chennai as India’s leading east coast box port. First major corporatized port at Ennore (Phase 1, Coal handling berth) was completed this year. Tamil Nadu Electricity Board (TNEB) is installing coal handling equipment. The Jawaharlal Nehru Port Trust (JNPT), which has attained super-port status because of its efficiency and productivity, is now focussing on marketing internationally. It was handling around 1.2 million containers annually and is expected to touch 1.4 million containers by December 2001. The efficiency and productivity of the port has visibly improved over the past three years. International shippers earlier preferred Colombo or other parts in west Asia. However, JNPT is now receiving cargo from Karachi to be further dispatched. The port has also attracted cargo from the gulf countries, which were earlier going to Dubai. JNPT is further augmenting its facilities to cater to international shippers. The port has a linear quay length of 680 metre, six rail-mounted quay cranes, two super post panamax, rubber-tyred and rail-mounted gantry cranes, and will be adding additional container berths. The port handles around 70 per cent of the inland container depot products of the Concor at Nagpur. A study is underway to convert JNPT’s four bulk berths into container berths. The Mumbai Port Trust (MbPT) failed to receive bids for licencing of the five terminals at Victoria Dock as multipurpose berths for cargo operations. Bids were invited for licencing of the five terminals with 13 berths for five years, extendable as may be mutually agreed. Transport Policy The 52nd Report of Parliamentary Standing Committee on Transport has recommended that there is no need for a regulatory authority for ports such as the Tariff Authority for Major Ports (TAMP). In the present scenario of modernization and corporatization, major ports should have the liberty to fix port tariff. Major ports also face competition from minor and state ports. The proposal to convert TAMP into an appellate tribunal, as suggested by the C. Babu Rajeev Committee, has evoked stiff resistance from none other that the TAMP Chairman himself. TAMP has also sought legislative powers from the union government to levy fees for services provided. It has urged the government to formalize the arrangement of audit of its accounts by the Comptroller and Auditor General of India (CAG). At present, TAMP is totally dependent on the government for budgetary support. As long as this arrangement continues, the prescription of an accounts format and CAG audit are necessary. TAMP has also urged the government to hold prior consultations with the tariff regulator before making investments and awarding BOT concessions to the private sector, as the royalties paid to major ports and the revenues shared with them will affect the tariffs of BOT operators. Besides, the creation of assets will have significant tariff implications. Inland Waterways India has 14,500 km of navigable waterways of which 5,700 km are navigable by mechanized vessels. There are three national waterways. These include Allahabad-Haldia, Dhubri-Sadiya over Brahmaputra and Kottapurram-Kollam on the west coast canal. The cabinet has approved the Inland Waterways Authority of India (IWAI) Amendment Bill 2001 to enable it to constitute the IWAI. The policy package for the sector will allow the authority to form joint ventures with private sector companies. The new policy also allows equity participation for joint ventures upto 40 per cent for BOT projects and grants tax exemption as offered in the infrastructure sector. Major private and public sector companies, including Hindustan Lever Ltd, Indo Gulf Corporation, NTPC, Numaligarh Refineries and Concor, have evinced interest in developing inland water transport facilities in the country. Railways The Railway ministry has opposed the idea of corporatization of the organization as proposed by the Planning Commission’s approach paper to the Tenth Plan. However, a beginning at restructuring seems to be in sight with the Railways agreeing to corporatize some of its non-core activities. The ministry feels that corporatization of the entire organization would not bring significant benefits. The Khanna Committee Report released in February 2001 sharply criticized the role of the Railway ministry, especially in not maintaining correct data on accidents and the action taken on the reports of the enquiry committees. Its recommendations included merger of departments, closer interaction with overseas research agencies to improve crashworthiness of coaches, closure of railway lines where state governments are unwilling to bear losses, dropping projects for which only token allocation of funds has been made, total freeze on gauge conversion projects and reduction of staff strength by 25 per cent over the next ten years. The Rakesh Mohan Committee Report The Rakesh Mohan Committee comprising 17 members, was constituted on 31 December 1998. It submitted its The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 final report, outlining among other things, a financing plan to make the Railways a commercially viable organization. The committee has recommended major restructuring followed by eventual corporatization of the Railways. This includes disbanding of the present Railway Board, forming an Indian Railways Corporation to be governed by the Indian Railways Executive Board, and constituting an Indian Rail Regulatory Authority. The group has challenged the monopoly of railway officials over the transportation monolith by recommending lateral induction of experts other than railway officials into the executive board. It does not appear that this measure will be implemented. Broad suggestions made in the report are given in Box 3.1.3. Pipelines The pipeline sector has been creating new capacity away from the public gaze. The private sector is willing to invest 49 here even though it is inherently a monopolistic sector. However, no big player wants to be left out even though a regulatory framework is not in place. An interesting tussle has brewed between Gujarat, which has passed an act and Gas Authority of India Limited—a central government PSU—is disinclined to be regulated by a state regulator. Gujarat enacted the Gujarat Gas (Regulation of Transmission, Supply, and Distribution) Act in March, 20008. This has enabled the state to start a Rs 3,000 crore gas grid project of the Gujarat State Petroleum Corporation (GSPC). The project involves setting up a 2,500 km grid for the transportation of indigenous gas and imported liquefied natural gas (LNG) throughout the state. For this purpose GSPC, in which the state government has an 80 per cent stake, acts as the nodal agency. A special purpose vehicle, the Gujarat State Petronet Limited (GSPL), has been floated to own the assets. The grid will connect the Box 3.1.3 The Rakesh Mohan Committee Report Within the Indian Railways (IR), there is no controversy on rationalization of passenger fare and making it immune from political interference. However, the high growth targets set by the committee do not seem to be palatable. The committee has emphasized that competition has been increasing in the transportation business. In the 1980s, road transportation grew rapidly, eroding the share of the Railways, including the area of commodities where the Railways had traditional stronghold. The annual growth rate, measured in ‘net tonne kilometres’, averaged 5.33 per cent between 1984 to 1991 and dropped to 1.86 per cent during the next eight years (1992–9). Road dominance is likely to increase even further after the four-laning of the ‘Golden Quadrilateral’ and the development of new expressways in the country. The increasing use of pipelines for the transportation of POL products is likely to further reduce demand for their transportation. These developments call for a basic change in IR’s approach to freight transportation. Total passenger kilometers (pkm) had been growing at a trend rate of about 4.5 per cent over the last 15 year period, and the last five years have seen an acceleration to about 5.8 per cent. The patterns for physical volumes show a significant increase in the share of the upper classes, particularly after the 1980s, but the overwhelming share remains in the lower classes. The ratio of average passenger fare to the average freight tariff is amongst the lowest in the world. The railways, therefore, has to invest and reorganize in a significant fashion over the next few years in order to meet the rising demand of passenger business and, growing, but intensely, competitive freight business. Wrong pricing policies, inefficient public enterprise operations and other difficulties have all contributed to this situation. But the solution does not lie in borrowing funds, without improvements in returns. Expansion of traffic on high density routes to raise the speed of freight trains significantly requires both managerial action and investments in new technology. The existing managerial, financial and accounting systems are inadequate to meet the challenges ahead. IR also has to undergo major structural change in its organization if it is to serve the emerging needs of the country; this is the considered view of the expert group. The group has estimated that if there are no significant changes in performance, it would have an operating deficit of Rs 3700 crore by 2003. The challenges and concerns that lie ahead are: • • • • • Growing customer needs and rising expectations Lack of goal and task clarity Outdated organizational structure Lack of autonomy Undue political influence at all levels of decision making The expert committee particularly stressed the need for organizational change. The overwhelming sentiment is that action is overdue and ‘business as usual’ would be disastrous. The view of the expert group is that the potential exists to double the underlying rate of growth of IR. The stage of development favours the growth of rail especially freight. Accepting anything less would be a loss to the nation. The rail system is too important to permit its withering away. 8 On salient features of the Act and on its hopefully not ‘still’ birth pangs see Section 6.2. 50 India Infrastructure Report 2002 state’s gas-supplying centres with users, chiefly power plants. The act also envisages setting up of a regulatory authority. The Ministry of Petroleum and Natural Gas has taken up cudgels on GAIL’s behalf and has asked the state to reexamine the act on the grounds that would not only make the hitherto unanswerable GAIL comply with more than one regulatory authority but would also conflict with its interests. The central government is taking a myopic view of the real import of the Gujarat Gas Act. The main purpose of the act is to ensure the growth of the gas industry in the state. But since most of the LNG terminals are being conceived and built in Gujarat, the act would ensure the growth of the gas industry of the country as well. It also lays down a well-defined structure for the evolution of the gas industry, as well as the principles of regulation. And contrary to GAIL’s misplaced fears, the regulatory framework being introduced in the state is a light-handed one and does not regulate the price of gas. This has been rightly left to the market to decide as there is already a competition among gas sellers, and between gas and other fuels. The regulator would only regulate gas transmission charges. With regard to GAIL’s apprehensions that its existing infrastructure would become available to third parties, GAIL ought to realize that gas pipelines are a natural monopoly and hence should be regulated on the basis of the common carrier principle where all the companies should have open access at a fair price. Accordingly, the Gujarat Gas Act has been formulated to provide for regulation of gas transmission and distribution on an equitable basis. Airports The government is planning to introduce an integrated civil aviation policy which will incorporate guidelines on transport and tourism. It has been decided to club transport and tourism with aviation policy as good road and rail connectivity with airports would help both tourism and trade. The centre is also considering the appointment of an independent economic regulator for airports to fix airport tariff and safeguard public interest. An autonomous statutory Airports Economic Regulatory Authority (AERA) has been proposed as a long-term measure for the limited economic regulation of airports in view of the inherent monopoly characteristics of airport services. The regulator will be delinked from government control. The issue of setting up a regulatory authority has come in the wake of the government initiative of permitting complete foreign investment in airports. The government has approved the construction of new airports at Devenhally in Bangalore, Shamshabad in Hyderabad and Mopa in Goa, with majority private sector participation. The government decided to give major airports on longterm lease to private operators. The bidding process is well underway. There still needs to be the requisite amendment to the Airports Authority Act 1994. The aviation establishment has broadly come to an understanding that it would adopt a dual-component scheme of leasing. The first would be a one-time, fixed payment for the entire duration; and the second, a variable annual payment. It is estimated that the revenue from the leases of the four major airports would be sufficient to sustain the development and maintenance of the remaining 119 airports across the country. The Airport Authority of India (AAI) presently earns an annual revenue of approximately Rs 1,800 crore; of which nearly Rs 1,000 crore is generated by the airports at Delhi, Mumbai, Chennai and Kolkata. The AAI has been privatizing other airport services as well. The operation, maintenance and management of the centre for perishable cargo for exports at the Indira Gandhi International Airport has been given to a private operator last year. Integrated Transport NHAI is now looking at linking the high-density Golden Quadrilateral to points of high economic potential. To start with, the authority is interested in connecting 12 major ports to the highway network in a bid to attract more traffic. NHAI is in the process of establishing SPVs for the Haldia, JNPT and Vizag ports. The other ports that have been identified for connectivity are Kandla, Cochin, Paradip, Tuticorin and Marmugoa. NHAI is keen on the SPV route after it successfully implemented its first SPV project in the Moradabad bypass last year. It plans to invest 30 per cent in each project and raise the balance from the market. In the future, NHAI proposes to offload its stake in the SPV Company and generate earnings. The idea is to create a ‘rolling stock’ of earnings via disinvestment. The proceeds would be reinvested in future projects where NHAI proposes to take equity. The Container Corporation of India (Concor) is planning to launch dedicated freight trains with fixed time schedules for arrivals and departures between Shalimar (Howrah) and Mumbai, and Shalimar and Nagpur. The launching dates are yet to be finalized as demand estimates are being worked out. Concor has already launched similar dedicated freight trains with fixed time schedules between Shalimar and Chennai (July 2000), Shalimar and Hyderabad (November 2000) and Cossipore (Kolkata) and New Delhi (March 2000), for domestic traffic; and Cossipore and Haldia dock (May 2001) for international traffic. All services, but for the last, are doing well. Urban Infrastructure Urban infrastructure is particularly neglected. The deteriorating infrastructure for drinking water compelled the Eleventh Finance Commission to sound a cautionary note The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 on the inadequate maintenance of civic services and the need for rationalization in pricing of urban services. It has called for increase of tax revenue and user charges to cover operation and maintenance expenses. The commission also mentioned the need for speeding up devolution of funds and a concomitant transfer of staff from state governments to local bodies in line with the 74th Amendment. Progress along better quality private participation and investments has been slow due to inadequate revenue streams. However, a few states have been attempting innovative ways of construction and financing. The progress in municipal bond markets has been very little. The credibility of urban local bodies (ULBs) which 51 had raised money earlier has come under cloud as ULBs lack financial management skills. Their accounting is not in line with generally accepted practices. For example, the Nashik Municipal Corporation failed to open an escrow account (a key bond issue condition) even two years after the bond issue, setting back the nascent market. The deliberations on National Water Policy and Report of the Sukthankar Committee were two important policy initiatives last year. Whereas the first raised the important issue of sharing of water resources—mainly surface water— among different states for different usage, the second one detailed the complexity of drinking water in urban and rural areas. The latter also highlighted complex institutional Box 3.1.4 The Sukthankar Committee Report The Government of Maharashtra (GOM) established a committee to prepare a roadmap for improved provision of water and sewerage in rural and urban areas under the chairmanship of Mr. D.M. Sukthankar, former chief secretary of Maharashtra (GOM 2001c). The committee was to suggest future strategy for O&M for existing and new schemes, the framework of an institution for tariff setting, feasibility and means of private sector participation in the water sector and to suggest effective implementation of the Ground Water Act 1993. The government had perceived the problems as the non-collection of water tariff, funds not being allocated for O&M, and lack of trained manpower with ULBs. The committee however, found that allocation of funds for O&M through budgetary process had completely failed and local government accounts are not maintained properly. There was lack of accountability within ULBs. Water leakages are as high as 50 per cent, new water schemes do not meet local needs. There was an emphasis on construction rather than O&M, and at best they supplied ‘some’ water rather than good quality water in adequate quantities. The Committee made many suggestions, of which the important ones are: • Villages should have self-sustainable single village schemes. In smaller rural areas, community driven approaches need to be initiated. The government should empower local institutions (zilla parishads and gram panchayats) and user groups (village water committees) to assume the lead role in decision making and operations. Village schemes should be integrated water resources management (90 per cent of rural water schemes depend on ground water) ensuring source sustainability at local level. The funds from the state government must be directly transferred to village water and sanitation committees, who should have freedom to procure the services from the community and market. Multi-village schemes should be constructed where sustainable source of water is not locally available. • Larger urban areas generally require larger piped water supply schemes. There need to be a commercial orientation. City water and sewage establishments (CWSEs) should be set up independently (as a municipal undertaking, company under the Companies Act, or co-operative societies under the Co-operative Society Act). The CWSEs should enter into long-term concessions (25–30 years) with private firms, selected on a competitive basis. CWSEs should mobilize their own investment resources from the market on a commercial basis (through capital market, domestic financial institutions or the proposed state revolving fund or bond bank). • Maharashtra had enacted the Ground Water Act 1993, which gave priority to ground water for drinking use. The Act primarily relates to drinking water, but the state lacked political will to enforce it. Hence, the state needs to set up a Maharashtra Gr ound Water Regulatory Authority (MGRA) with provision for regulation of all uses of groundwater including irrigation, establishment of independent local watershed management units, and community management. • The report points out that over extraction of ground water is a direct result of free electricity provided to villagers. The government should change the economic price of electricity for pumpsets so as to prevent over-drawing of ground water. As groundwater rights are chattel to land ownership, it would be useful to explore the introduction of a community rights framewor k for water resources, including ground water. • The committee strongly recommended the establishment of an independent Maharashtra Water and Wastewater Regulatory Commission so that abuse of the local monopoly of the CWSEs does not take place. The Commission could also regulate the existing local bodies (both urban and rural) to create incentives for restructuring at the local level. • The Maharashtra Jeevan Pradhikaran (MJP), a state parasatal body responsible for design and construction of water and wastewater schemes in urban and rural areas and mobilization of resources on behalf of local bodies, must be restructured. MJP needs to establish independent corporate entities. The main (future) role for MJP should be limited to project design and construction supervision. The committee recommended incentive based disbursement of state funds to urban, local and village bodies. 52 India Infrastructure Report 2002 arrangement in Maharashtra, which is similar to many other states. Draft National Water Policy 1998: The National Water Resources Council did not accept the Draft National Water Policy in its meeting held in July 2000. The working group, set up to study the draft, consisted of water resources ministers from all states. It discussed the draft and guidelines for water allocation among states. The states were vertically divided with regard to River Basin Organizations (RBOs). The issues remained unresolved for the following reasons: • Participants did not want RBOs with statutory powers as they did not find them in consonance with the constitutional provisions and the spirit of the federal structure. • Some states felt that the priorities with regard to water allocation should be drinking water, irrigation, hydel power, aquaculture, agro-industries, non-agricultural industries and navigation and other uses. They felt that the Inter-state Water Disputes Act 1956 could be suitably reviewed and amended to provide for conciliatory powers in Section 4 (1), timeframe for constitution of tribunal, completion and adjudication by the tribunal and for publication of award by the union government. • A few states are of the opinion that the policy and guidelines appeared to have been drafted to accommodate the narrow interests of a few privileged states. • Some states felt that the centre was trying to take control over the rivers and other water resources through this policy. The working group eventually decided to constitute a core group of ministers under the chairmanship of the Union Minister of State for Water Resources to go into the details of water allocation and the setting up of an RBO. The final definition of provisions coined by the core group relating to water sharing is: The water sharing/distribution amongst the states should be guided by a national perspective with due regard to water resources availability and needs within the river basin. This statement is open to several interpretations. The group also decided not to empower the proposed RBOs with statutory powers. Water conservation, its importance and limitations: One of the main proponent of water conservation, Rajendra Singh, who strongly believes in community rights of water, water harvesting and water conservation received the Magsaysay Award in 2001 for his work in Alwar, Rajathan. His work is a good example of integrated water system at village/ community level which is also an economically efficient solution for drinking water. It has proved that systematic development of village level watershed can change the economics of the village community. The strategy of water harvesting and surface water development was through a series of check weirs and earthen dams, soil conservation through series of gully plugs, afforestation and agro-forestry to meet the requirement of fodder, fuel and fruit as well as for soil conservation. There are many other successful examples of water harvesting in Madhya Pradesh, Andhra Pradesh and Maharashtra at village/community level. A few state governments have extended the concept of water harvesting to a city level and have passed resolutions that all new dwellings should have water harvesting devices on their roof. These are simple devices. The seasonal availability of water limits its use but this will help in recharging the groundwater table. Development at state level: The chosen method adopted by states to build urban infrastructure is ‘partnership’ with the private sector. State governments short of funds have taken initiatives to establish infrastructure fund/project development companies in partnership with private sector financial institutions. The role of these institutions is to bridge the gap of risk perceived by a private promoter and the risk perceived by the present provider of the service. These are developments in the right direction. Not all the institutions are of the same genre, nor is it proposed that they have similar functions. Table 3.1.3 captures succinctly different types of institutions. Generally, these institutions are referred to as Infrastructure Initiative Funds (IIF). Infrastructure for the Agriculture Sector The government has finally realized that the value addition in agriculture sector is constrained by poor infrastructure. To mitigate this constraint, it announced the first ever National Agricultural Policy and set a target of more than 4 per cent per annum growth over the next two decades. A significant development has been the announcement of a National Policy on Handling, Storage and Transportation of Food Grains with the objective to harness efforts and resources of public and private sectors, both domestic and foreign, to develop the requisite infrastructure. The government accorded ‘infrastructure status’ for bulk grain handling and transportation, and incentives have been extended. Further, the government guarantees utilization of this infrastructure. Twenty locations have been identified in grain producing centres, consuming centres and port towns for integrated bulk handling and storage along with testing facilities and quality control. Punjab’s agro marketing co-operative Markfed, has prepared a blueprint to provide adequate storage for 10 million tons of wheat by setting up hi-tech modern silos. Private sector participation is also envisaged. India is the world’s second largest producer of fruits and vegetables. However, more than 30 per cent of the produce The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 53 Table 3.1.3 Some Examples of Infrastructure Initiative Funds (IIFs) Model (Main Pupose) Examples and Partner Agency Applicability and Implications Dedicated IIF Pure Project Development APIIF (in partnership with IL&FS) UPIIF PIIF Integrated IIF Project Development & Funding I-DECK TNUDF State Owned Project Development Company (PDC) I-KIN I-WIN PDCOR Other Forms FFUIDC (Feedback Finance Urban Infrastructure Development Company) is apparently ‘wasted’ in the absence of proper storage and processing facilities. A subsidy of Rs 78 crore for setting up cold storages for perishable commodities was provided during 2000–1. It is now proposed to extend the coverage of the scheme to cover rural godowns. The subsidy to be provided by the government would be suitably enhanced to take care of this. The 2001 Budget proposed a number of initiatives. Important among them was: total exemption of excise duty on processed fruits and vegetables, credit linked subsidy schemes for construction of cold storage in villages and establishment of agri-business centres and agri-clinics. Notwithstanding the new government initiatives, the sector remained moribund by wide ranging restrictions that have been imposed on inter-state movement, storage and stocking of food grains and agriculture products. • Necessary where project definition processes of departments are inadequate • IIF can take proactive role in identifying projects and developing them on its own initiative • State government should be willing to allocate funds to IIF without seeking significant returns • Mechanism must exist for IIF recommendations to be implemented by respective state government departments • Viable developed projects to be supported by purely private funds. Non viable projects will devolve on the state government • Fund may be useful for credit enhancement of developed, support worthy projects • Funding support to projects independent of project development. Development of a project by IIF does not automatically entitle it to funding support by IIF • Required in situations where even beyond development, availability of funding for developed projects is a constraint • Impetus and motivation to initiate project development exercise must come from departments • State departments to reimburse PDC for expenses with suitable profits • PDC recommendations may be adopted by departments at their own discretion • Identify projects and develop them • Secure concessions from government • Implement projects through JV and invest in the equity of the JV CONCLUSION During the past year, many beginnings have been made. The transport sector—roads, ports, airports, and connectivity with ports—witnessed a flurry of activity which will improve infrastructure and reduce transport time. This could have major positive feed back effect on the economy. Railways have been provided a robust framework for change but have yet to respond positively—it is clearly caught in the crossconnections of vested interests. Power remained in the limelight, but without any physical improvement in the sector. Some cobwebs have hopefully been cleared and it is generally accepted that adequate user charges have to be levied, billed and collected if the sector is to see any improvement: the role of the government has to diminish. The telecom sector has demonstrated that competition can 54 India Infrastructure Report 2002 do what regulation and state control cannot. Deregulation brought cellular tariffs to nearly a tenth of what they were two years ago. Urban infrastructure remained long on promises and short on delivery. We are seeing emergence of new realism at the state level. What we are witnessing among the states is ‘institutional competition’. As states compete, and some do visibly better than others, rulers and administrators would have to mend their ways to move forward. All state governments have come to realize that there is no alternative to competition and public-private partnership in infrastructure. 3.2 WLL, GOVERNANCE, CORPORATIZATION, AND SWANS: A REVIEW OF INSTITUTIONAL DEVELOPMENTS Rekha Jain The telecom sector witnessed several developments over the year. The government decided to allow ‘limited’ mobility in the wireless local loop (WLL). This brought the jurisdictional boundaries of various fixed service providers (FSPs); agencies such as the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI), Department of Telecom (DoT), and the Prime Minister’s Office (PMO) over the issues of policy, pricing and allocation of spectrum (a scarce resource) into sharp focus. The Department of Telecom Services (DTS) and Department of Telecom Operations (DTO) were merged to form into a public sector company called Bharat Sanchar Nigam Limited (BSNL) with effect from 1 October 2000. The process of corporatization highlighted the need for prior ground work in evolving a road map and a blueprint of the strategy. The draft of the Convergence Bill which had been announced last year was made available to the public. The bill proposed setting up of the Communications Commission that was to be responsible for regulating both telecom and broadcast sectors. The bill did not specify the regulation of competition issues, and role and scope of the appellate board, a gap that could result in delays in resolving disputes. Other practical issues in implementing the Convergence Bill also arise. Several state governments—Gujarat, Andhra Pradesh, West Bengal and Rajasthan—have gone for stateswide area networks (SWANS). Others are likely to follow suit. Dedicated physical facilities especially cable links for SWANS need a re-examination, given the growth of the internet, the networking of Internet Service Providers (ISPs), and the resulting possibility of virtual networks. Even after the setting up of TRAI in 1997, the policy and part of the regulatory function continued to be with the Telecom Commission. The creation of TRAI should have also led to redefinition of the role of Telecom Commission and DoT, but this was not done satisfactorily. In the creation of various departments (DTS and DTO) from the DoT), the department had attempted to separate the policy functions from the operations9. Amalgamation of DTS and DTO and the subsequent corporatization led to the creation of BSNL and the DoT, the erstwhile Telecom Commission. This streamlined the structure by a separation of the policy and regulatory function (responsibility of DoT) and the actual operations (BSNL). Thus there is still much overlap between TRAI’s and DoT’s defining rules. Currently DoT is responsible for policy formulation, licensing, spectrum management, administrative monitoring of public sector undertakings, research and development, and standardization/validation of equipment. Spectrum management and equipment standards are areas that are usually under the regulator’s purview in many countries. While the TRAI Act 1997 had precluded it from spectrum management, the TRAI Amendment Ordinance 2000 gave it only a recommendatory role for spectrum management and standards. The overlapping jurisdictions of TRAI and DoT has led to delays in the past as in the formulation of guidelines for opening up the domestic long distance market or resolution of issues arising out of the WLL (with limited mobility) case. Political Interventions In order to give the telecom sector a boost, the Prime Minister, Atal Behari Vajpayee set up a high powered group on telecom (GOT) in 1999 to evolve a policy framework for the sector. This was possibly done outside the DoT as it was felt that it may not be able to conceive radically different roadmap, or it may even thwart involvement of 9 This was not done as a part of any overall sector restructuring plan but under pressure from both Indian Telecom Service and Indian Administrative Service cadres to head DoT. The government’s inability to handle this issue effectively had resulted in the creation of these departments. (3iNetwork 2001, Section 8.1). The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 private sector or deregulation in its own limited vested interest. The GOT drafted the National Telecom Policy 1999. Another example of political interference was in a recent case when BSNL billed advance rental to its customers. The telecom minister intervened to say that it was a mistake and that these would not be charged. Such political interference in organizational issues would create impediments to an independent functioning and the fixing of responsibility for decisions. On its part BSNL did not inform the customers in advance and/or suggest alternative payment methods. For example, it could have suggested staggered payments or provided incentives to those who paid the entire amount at one go, thus smoothening the interaction with the customers. Role of regulatory agencies in the convergence bill: Even as the debate regarding the functioning of TRAI continues, the draft of the Convergence Bill provides for significant reorganization of the existing policy and regulatory institutions. The setting up of the Communications Commission would necessitate requisite review and redesign of the existing institutions such as TRAI and Prasar Bharti10. The Bill also envisages important changes in the powers of the existing bodies in areas such as licensing. For example, currently, while Ministry of Information and Broadcasting (I&B) is the licensor for broadcast licenses, DoT under the Ministry of Communications is the licensor for telecom licences. The Convergence Bill gives such powers to the Commission, thus significantly enhancing the scope of the proposed regulatory institution. In comparison, under the existing TRAI Amendment Ordinance (2000), TRAI has a recommendatory role in licensing with respect to the following: (a) need and timing for introduction of new service provider (b) terms and conditions of licence to a service provider; and (c) revocation of license for non-compliance of terms and conditions of license. Further TRAI’s function is to ‘ensure compliance of terms and conditions of license’. From this it is obvious that it has been hard for the government and the incumbent to give significant authority to TRAI despite its reorganization. It remains to be seen how the provision in the bill that gives even greater powers to new institutions than those currently existing would be accepted by the government. The bill itself has not been actively pursued for passage in parliament, as there has not been significant legislative activity in general 10 Prasar Bharati is a statutory autonomous body established under the Prasar Bharati Act. The Board came into existence from 23 November 1997. The Prasar Bharati is envisaged to be the public service broadcaster of the country. The objective of public service broadcasting is to be achieved through All India Radio and Doordarshan which earlier were working as independent media units under the Ministry of I and B. http://mib.nic.in/information&b/ AUTONOMUS/frames.htm. 55 since the inception of the bill. The lack of progress has been due to pressures from the opposition parties on the government’s handling of the situation arising out of the disclosures of the Tehelka tapes. Telecom and competition regulation: The key issue in telecom regulation is to design appropriate interventions that achieve both static and dynamic efficiency. Under the current regulatory framework, static efficiency is achieved through ex ante sector specific regulation (such as those related to licensing) and dynamic efficiency is aimed through ex post competition policies. While the ex ante regulation regarding licensing is in place and significant experience exists in this domain, the ex post regulation regarding competitive processes has yet to evolve. In the current multi-service provider regime, there are likely to be several mergers and acquisitions and scope for vertical integration in service provision. For example, Zee Networks and Siti Cable are business entities that provide various elements of what may become a vertically integrated service provider covering both telecom and broadcast service as well as content. This could lead to anticompetitive practices by their bundling of set top boxes, network and content to subscribers, effectively eliminating choice. Technological convergence also has implications for regulatory institution design. While on one hand convergent services require that boundaries of sector specific regulatory agencies be expanded, on the other it implies that general competition policy would play a greater role in the regulation. The other issue is the trade off between regulatory capture and sector specific skills (IIR, 2000, p. 69). A ‘convergent/ competition’ regulator is less prone to capture by players in a specific sector, due to the diversity of interests across sectors that is represented, although it may lack the technical expertise for managing the sector specific issues. Under the current regulatory regime issues related to monopolistic, restrictive, and unfair trade practices are to be handled by Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Commission (MRTPC) established under subsection 1 of Section 5 of the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act 1969. While the MRTPC itself has little teeth and is to be replaced by a Competition Commission, this framework recognizes the importance of managing competition. On the other hand, while the Convergence Bill provides for an Appellate Tribunal, it does not specify its scope. On this aspect the bill’s focus is procedure oriented as for example, in specifying the details of the procedures for handling cases that come before the Appellate Board. While appropriate regulatory institutional design is one possible way of dealing with competition and anticompetitive practices, the other could be through designing of licensing conditions. Such conditions could be ‘effects 56 India Infrastructure Report 2002 based’ general competition related conditions so that the onus of not indulging in anti-competitive practices is with the licensee. There are several examples of how competition related issues are handled in different countries. There are instances of sector specific regulation handling these issues (as in Canada) or sector specific regulator handling it along with competition specific agencies (as in UK, where Office of Telecommunications (Oftel) and Monopolies and Mergers Commissions as well as the Department of Trade and Industry, the policy making body for telecom have a clear role and authority in competition related issues). (3iNetwork 2001, pp. 63–5) Independence of regulators: Currently both TRAI and Prasar Bharati have budgets allocated from the Consolidated Funds of India. This requires them to follow the employment, promotion and other rules and regulations as applicable to government departments, reducing their autonomy and restricting choices for appointments. TRAI has been perceived as following the government’s perspective rather than having an independent view. This has led to weakening of the regulatory process. Despite this lack of independence in TRAI the Convergence Bill has proposed that the Commission be dependent on government funding. The funds generated by the Commission by way of fees are to go to the Consolidated Fund of India and its budget is to be passed by Parliament. Further, the employees of the Commission and the Appellate Tribunal are to be appointed, as well as their salaries and other conditions of service are to be determined, by the central government. In addition, the Secretary General, who will play a very important role in the functioning of the Commission will be only on deputation from the central government. These points seem to compromise the independence and autonomy of these two bodies. The Bill needs to specify the creation of a ‘Convergence Fund’ that would have contributions from the service providers for financing the Commission’s operations. In USA, Canada and UK, regulatory agencies do not have independent sources of income. In USA, the FCC (Federal Communications Commission), which is funded by the Congress, has traditionally been sensitive to its wishes. However Commissioners have been known to take decisions contrary to Congress when they have felt that the President or the courts would support them. Independence in views is also brought about by requiring that not more than three out of five Commissioners be from a single political party. In UK Oftel’s budget is approved by the Parliament, whereas running costs are met from license fee which are roughly proportional to the operators turnover. Despite dependence on the Parliament, Oftel has shown considerable independence in decision-making. Besides overlooking the provision of financial autonomy, the bill also provides for the central government to issue all sorts of specific directives relating to licensing that will be binding on the Commission, thus further compromising the independence of the Commission. The role of the government ought to have been limited only to the issue of general policies and the Commission should have been able to determine the implementation. Spectrum management: TRAI and DoT have to work out an equitable method of allocation of spectrum between fixed and cellular services. In addition, there is a need to put in place a mechanism for spectrum allocation that is applicable to different types of sectors such as telecom, broadcast and Information Technology (IT). Traditionally most regulators have different allocative mechanisms for telecom and broadcasting sectors. Spectrum for broadcast in the United States was allocated freely owing to the ‘public interest’ component embedded in such services. This had enabled a certain kind of regulatory oversight over television, which may not have been possible otherwise. The advent of the internet and new models of service provision, such as bundling of telecom, cable, and internet services, requires an examination of these regulatory policies. The lower levels of content regulation on the internet are likely to put pressures on regulatory agencies to lower content supervision over television. As a consequence it may become necessary for the government to review its broadcast spectrum allocation processes. This need becomes more critical in a fast changing technological scenario in which broadcast services turn digital and internet becomes the delivery channel for different types of services including telecom. By treating spectrum for these services differentially, the government in effect dictates the technology for services thus preventing the market from making those choices. The issue of service specific licenses can be dealt with by having two level licensing––infrastructure license and spectrum license. The idea is to delink particular bands of spectrum from specific types of service. For efficient management of spectrum, the Wireless Planning and Coordination Wing should evolve a time table for moving government agencies currently using spectrum in the commercial bands to other bands. Further, all agencies whether government or private, should pay for the spectrum. The governments’ payment of such charges will make explicit the subsidies inherent in the provision of those services that use spectrum. It will also tend to allow for more efficient use of spectrum and help find alternative technologies for services that do not necessarily find wireless to be cost effective. STATE WIDE AREA NETWORKS FOR GOVERNANCE Although SWANs were designed with the objective of providing e-governance, the slow pace of development of The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 applications had led to its limited use predominantly for voice and video conferencing. While the build operate transfer framework is useful for infrastructure development, the basic issue of developing dedicated infrastructure to serve the objectives of a SWAN need to be questioned. With the proliferation of internet usage and internet service providers, achieving the same objectives through internet would be possible. However, the need for appropriate application interfacing and last mile access would still remain. The current application development process that drives the e-governance initiatives should include more citizens’ participation and be more citizen centric. It should also span across departments. Data validation and maintenance are critical tasks that need to be undertaken in a systematic manner. A usability review could be helpful in evolving a portfolio of applications for maintenance. Currently very few applications are available on SWANs. Given the current status of application development, project structures that include stringent service level agreements drive the cost of implementation high. Currently state governments bear all the revenue risk. By explicitly sharing such risks, the focus would turn towards those applications that citizens are most willing to pay for. The government may also be required to provide applications that do not generate revenue (access by poor people). By explicitly stating such requirements, the costs and subsequent subsidies can be better targeted. A realistic demand assessment for bandwidth for such networked applications, based on the nature of applications (several types of applications do not necessarily need a network e.g. land record applications) needs to drive the requirements. CREATION OF BSNL Although Mahanagar Telephone Nigam Ltd. and Videsh Sanchar Nigam Ltd. were corporatized in 1986 and there had been talk of corporatization of DoT since the submission of Athreya Committee report in March 1991, the process of corporatization of BSNL was done in a hurry. The consultants were given a very short time to prepare a report. They have been subsequently retained to help in the restructuring. The corporatization process was not smooth. Prior to the corporatization, the employees, both in the workers and officers categories went on strike, paralysing the service provision and managed to get their demands met. The demands included salary increases, a ‘no retrenchment policy’ and the requirement to pay their pensions from the Consolidated Fund of India and not a general fund set up for this process as is normally done for other public sector organizations. 57 In several countries, corporatization has been brought about after enactment of law/s that created the organization, specified the functions and defined the corresponding regulatory framework. Often this has required concurrent changes to other Acts so as to bring about a smooth transition11. The corporatization of BSNL was affected without legislative changes. The employees concerns regarding the provision of provident fund led to prolonged strikes. The organizational structure of BSNL consists of a Chairman and Managing Director, supported by a board consisting of five members—finance, planning, operation, human resources, commercial and network services. Additional external members are yet to be inducted. The full time board members are from within the erstwhile DTS/DTO/DoT. It is well recognized that external ( to the government and the company) board members can bring in the required differences in perspective necessary for growth. The requirement of external directors is mandatory as per SEBI (Securities and Exchange Board of India) guidelines for large companies. However, no time frame has been stipulated by the government for this induction on the BSNL board. The corporatization process had little immediate impact as few changes had been made in the existing administrative structures. The many levels of hierarchical structures need to be reviewed, and a flatter structure that could be more responsive needs to be devised. The consultant’s task is to suggest the appropriate organizational form and process12. After corporatization BSNL has been structured as a single organization. For administrative ease, it has been divided into circles, roughly corresponding to state boundaries. However, if privatization is to take place BSNL would need to be divided either along business lines or along geographical regions, as otherwise it would be difficult to find investors with the requisite financing. The separation could create problems as some of the resulting units (such as the local business when divided along business 11 For example, in Malaysia legislation was enacted in 1987 to separate the Jabatan Telekom Malaysia (JTM), the government department responsible for telecommunications into two parts—the regulatory unit called JTM and an operating company called Syarikat Telekom Malaysia (STM), a government owned company. STM was later privatized into Telekom Malaysia by selling off its stake to private and institutional investors. Suitable amendments were also made to the Employees Provident Fund Act and Pension Act to protect employees’ interests and enable them to continue with provident fund facility in the new organization. 12 In contrast, in UK, the corporatization and the subsequent privatization were preceded by changes in the board composition. Several other changes were made to BT’s structure within the framework of a white paper that outlined the roadmap for the privatization. This plan was reviewed periodically. 58 India Infrastructure Report 2002 lines or the eastern region when divided geographically) may not be attractive to investors. As the road map of privatization has not been spelt out, it is difficult for the organization to prepare itself for the future. This uncertainty has led to a low morale of the employees. BSNL plans to get into cellular service provision. But its roll-out seems hesitant. In this segment, private operators have had a head start and have developed the marketing expertise, customer databases and infrastructure. For example, MTNL’s cellular services have been able to register only 10,000 customers in New Delhi and around 8,000 in Mumbai compared to Bharti’s nearly 33,000 in Delhi for Bharti and BPL’s 27,000 in Mumbai (as of April 2001), the dominant operators in the two cities (see the COAI website). Therefore, to make a success of the cellular operations, BSNL may need to create a separate entity that could be staffed by people with a greater market orientation than that available in BSNL. Such an entity would need to work on a commercially-oriented manner with management having the autonomy to give commissions to sales staff; flexible payment structures; ability to price competitively; give discretion and responsibility to staff; salaries linked to performance or targets––attributes that are absent in BSNL’s operations today. International long distance could be an area of expansion for BSNL. Exploiting value added services would require cultural, overhaul in the organization. As BSNL changes towards becoming a corporate entity in practice, a key requirement would be the implementation of commercially oriented accounting systems including management control systems. Such a system would require not only basic changes to the existing accounting systems right down to the field level, but also training and significant computerization to implement the system. Given the long decision cycles in the government, and the massive investments required, such a system will require a dedicated project team that would have to have the requisite financial powers and technical understanding of the management issues in computerization. Corporatization thus far has not changed the earlier decision making structures and processes. There is a need to train managers to have a business perspective and build accountability for performance, an aspect that is lacking in most government departments. For example, it will have to develop performance norms as per the new technology inducted and move away from an earlier culture where employees demanded to be evaluated on performance as per the norms of older technology, causing low productivity and additional costs for the network. For example, the number of DELs (Direct Exchange Lines) per employee in BSNL (Table 3.2.1) is low, not only in comparison to developed countries but also in comparison to countries such as Indonesia and Philippines. From a monopoly mind set where BSNL was used to treating customers as though doing them a favour by providing services, it will have to change to being more sensitive to customer needs. This change is very critical and is going to determine whether BSNL continues to be a profit making entity. Appropriate systems need to be designed for facilitating customer interactions. For example, instead of expecting customers to come to its premises to pick up forms, these could be widely distributed through retail channels and the web. While it has started distribution of some forms through the web, it needs to do so for all its services. Similarly, a variety of options for payment of bills could be offered. Such systems need to be designed for the different elements of service. With corporatization costs are being treated and reported more appropriately. The costs of its inefficient operations were hidden and paid for by the tax payers are now revealed in its lower profits. BSNL does have tremendous strengths vis-à-vis Table 3.2.1 Comparison of Telecom Indicators in Different Countries Country Denmark TDC Tele Denmark Indonesia Philippines France Telecom(10 countries) France (France Telecom) South Africa Argentina Singapore (Singtel) Japan(NTT) India(BSNL) Year No. of Lines 2000 2000 2000 2000 2000 2000 2000 2000 2000 2000 1999 3735000 3400000 6662065 1999922 3.9E+07 3.4E+07 5075417 3723936 NA 2.2E+07 No of Employees 18363 10900 37705 13285 188866 148846 60613 10259 NA 224000 431874 Number of Lines per Employee 203.40 311.93 176.69 150.54 207.55 229.19 83.73 362.99 NA 50.00 Source www.teledammark.dk www.telkom.co .id www.pldt.com.ph ww.francetelecom.com.fr ww.francetelecom.com.fr www.telkom.co.za www.telecom.com.ar www.sinftel.com www.ntt.co.jp ww.dotindia.com The Infrastructure Sector in India, 2000–1 competition, in terms of its reach and trained personnel. But to build upon it would need full autonomy. That could prove difficult. CONVERGENCE BILL HIGHLIGHTS Key highlights of the Convergence Bill drafted by a committee under Fali Nariman: • Formation of a single commission that would address both content and carriage regulation. • The enactment of this Act would lead to a repeal of the Indian Telegraph Act 1885, Indian Wireless Telegraphy Act 1933, Telegraph Unlawful Possession Act 1950 and the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India Act 1997. • Licensing as a key function: (The Ministry of Communications for telecom; and the Ministry of Information and Broadcasting for FM Radio. MAJOR FUNCTIONS COMMISSION • OF THE REGULATORY Licensing 59 • Determination of tariffs • Formulation and determination of conditions of fair and equitable access • Promotion of competition • Protection of consumer interests • Promotion and enforcement of universal service obligations • Formulation of advertising codes for content application services • Formulation of commercial codes in respect of communication services and network infrastructure facilities • Taking steps to regulate or curtail the harmful and illegal content on the internet and other communication services • Formulation of codes and technical standards and norms to ensure quality and interoperability of services and network infrastructure facilities (including equipment) • Carrying out any study and publishing findings on matters of importance to the consumers, service providers and the communications industry • Institutionalizing appropriate mechanisms and interaction on a continual basis with all sectors of industry and consumers so as to facilitate and promote the basic objectives of the Act. REFERENCES 3iNetwork (2001), India Infrastructure Report 2001: Issues in Regulation and Market Structure, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. COA/(2000) http://www.coai.com. Government of Gujarat (2001), The Gujarat Gas (Regulation of Transmission, Supply and Distribution) Act 2001, Gandhinagar. Government of India (2000a), Draft Integrated Transport Policy, Planning Commission, New Delhi. —— (2000b), Draft National Water Policy (1998), Ministry of Water Resources, New Delhi. —— (2001a), Report of the Expert Group—Settlement of SEB Dues, Planning Commission, New Delhi. —— (2001b), Report of the Expert Group—Restructuring of SEBs, Planning Commission, New Delhi. —— (2001c), The Electricity Bill 2001, New Delhi. —— (2001d), The Indian Railways Report: Policy Imperatives for Reinvention and Growth, Expert Group on Indian Railways, Indian Railways, New Delhi. —— (2001e), 52nd Report on the Ministry of Shipping, The Parliamentary Standing Committee on Transport and Tourism. Government of Karnataka (2000), Report of the High Level Committee on Escrow Cover to IPPs to Government of Karnataka, Banglore. Government of Maharashtra (2001a), Report of the Energy Review Committee Part I, Mumbai. _________ (2001b), Report of the Energy Review Committee Part II, Mumbai. _________ (2001c), The Sukthankar Committee Report on Operation, Maintenance and Management of Rural and Urban Water Supply Schemes, Water Supply and Sanitation Department, Mumbai. Haldia Gajendra (2000), Indian Highways: A Framework for Commercialisation, National Council of Applied Economic Research, New Delhi. Singhal Rajrishi, Malini Goyal and Arindam Sengupta (2000), ‘Tomorrow’s CEO must be a Coach, Not Power-Base’, an interview with Jack Welch, Economic Times, 18 September. 60 India Infrastructure Report 2002 4 THE CONSTITUTIONAL AND LEGAL FRAMEWORK FOR GOVERNANCE 4.1 THE FRAMEWORK OF REGULATION T.C.A. Anant • Jaivir Singh One of the earliest and possibly the most often cited basis for government intervention in utility provision arises out of the ‘natural monopoly’ problem. Additional reasons for large-scale intervention in markets in less developed countries (LDCs) have been cited as arising out of capital market failures and, scale and scope economies. The traditional analysis of the regulation problem as a natural monopoly has tended to concentrate on price or quantity instruments, with little concern about the institutions within which such instruments are operationalized. An alternative perspective can be gleaned from the so-called new institutional economics literature on regulation. This literature exhorts us to be sensitive to the fact that public utility provision is characterized by long-term contracts, and therefore the regulator can itself be viewed as an agency that balances the interests of both the consumers and the providers of a service over a long period of time. If perceived in this manner, the regulation problem becomes tractable as an exercise in institutional analysis. Given the fiat to regulate, a regulator has to choose an appropriate instrument to achieve a regulatory end. This section discusses this issue and provides some examples of how the choice of such instruments can affect certain public outcomes. For instance, a strand of law and economics analysis offers insight into whether rights should be protected by using ‘property’ or ‘liability’ rules. The significance of instructional analysis in the study of infrastructure is immediately obvious once it is realized that many infrastructure projects involve the use of sunk capital, implying the presence of considerable asset specificity. The presence of such asset specificity makes public utility provision subject to risk because the provider has to invest in specialized assets that cannot be re-deployed without incurring substantial loss if the initial contract were to be disturbed in some manner. In other words, the opportunity cost of investment in many public utility endeavours is much higher in best the alternative use, should the initial transaction be prematurely terminated. This suggests that the decision to invest in a public utility can be forestalled on account of transaction cost considerations. The notion of transaction cost is particularly useful where transaction costs are perceived as the ex-ante costs of drafting, negotiating, and safeguarding agreements and the ex-post costs associated with continuing the transaction relationship over a period of time in the face of changing circumstances.1 In the presence of substantial transaction costs, institutions can be perceived as modes of organizing economic activity— set up to overcome transaction costs. The institution of the market cannot be expected to allocate resources in the presence of the problems associated with the infrastructure provision because standard contract doctrines constructed to govern discrete transactions are not equipped to handle the contractual complexity associated with these problems. In addition to the problem of provision, it needs to be noted that public utilities involve a large range of users, sometimes almost as large as the voting population. This implies that in addition to the concerns of contracting related transactions costs, providers of public goods have also to worry about the distribution of benefits and the valuation of benefits and costs across different segments of the target population. 1 Willamson (1985) offers an instructive analogy by stating that ‘Transaction costs are the economic equivalent of friction in physical systems’. The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 61 Thus, in addition to resolving issues of contract formation and adjudication, the provision of public utility services is involved with issues of distribution, equity, and fairness. Therefore, specialized structures of governance are required to mitigate the problems associated with public utilities. It has been suggested that regulation can provide such a structure, where the regulator is seen as an agent who devises, allocates, and administers a collective contract for the provision of some natural monopoly output. This effectively means, to use phrases coined by Goldberg, that the regulator has to achieve a balance by protecting the producer’s ‘right to serve’ against protecting the consumer’s ‘right to be served’ (Goldberg 1976). Conceptualizing regulation in this manner places an emphasis on mechanisms for maintaining, adjusting, and terminating long term relationships and also raises questions about the appropriate instruments one can use for effective regulation. The discussion on instruments has often been couched in terms of trade-offs between prices and quantities (tariffs vs. quotas), command and control vs. market based instruments as in the discussion of environmental issues, and property rules or liability rules in the discussions of law and economics. While an exhaustive discussion on the choice of optimal instruments is beyond the scope of this paper, the literature raises certain issues which have a bearing on our concern with regulatory design. We turn below to some of these issues. INSTRUMENTS OF REGULATION One line of inquiry has posed the regulation problem as the choice between setting a price or quantity signal to achieve a desired end. Another approach has asked whether one can best protect property rights, and therefore regulate, by using property rules or liability rules. Though both these strands focus on different choices, the conceptual similarity in delineating the problem is remarkable. In an idealized world with ‘no transactions costs’ the choice of instrument, and for that matter the nature of the regulator, is irrelevant. Prices vs. Quantities In the context of incomplete information, Weitzman (1974) has explored the choice between quantitative restrictions and price restrictions.2, 3 Suppressing all technical detail, it is useful to spell out the main results. Under conditions of incomplete information, quantity and price signals will transmit central commands in very different ways and will 2 Quantitative restrictions take the form of quotas in trade and capacity restrictions in production whereas price restrictions are imposed through tariffs, taxes, and subsidies. 3 See also Ray and Sen (1992) and Ray and Sen (1994). lead to different results. The question as to whether the quantity mode or the price mode is superior depends on a number of parameters, which include the shape of the benefit profiles. Briefly, quantity instruments perform the best when the benefit schedules are highly curved and the worst when benefit schedules are linear. On the other hand, price instruments perform the best when the benefit schedules are linear and the worst when the benefit schedules are highly curved. Thus, in the case of industrial pollutants, an industrial ‘bad’ such as those manifesting a quick and short horizon irreversible impact—for example poisonous gases— are more amenable to quantitative restrictions, while others which have a slow long term reversible impact may be better addressed through price controls. The distribution of technological knowhow across firms is another determinant. When the distribution of technological possibilities is limited with low variability, a price instrument has a high risk of failure. On the other hand, when the variability in the technological possibilities is large and a quantity rule specifying technology or cost is used, there is bound to be a considerable risk of ignoring a set of low cost technologies. One can view some of the possible policy measures affecting the telecom sector in this light and argue that the government is best advised not to specify technology in this sector; instead, it may be more appropriate to impose licence fees, taxes, or subsidies and let firms choose technology. Sometimes, in the presence of quantitative restrictions, regulators design provisions to sell or transfer licenses. If the sale or transfer of the licence does not change the nature, location, or type of the good on which quantitative restrictions have been placed, the key regulatory interest associated with changes in ownership will be centred primarily around anti-monopoly concerns. However, in certain cases the transfer or sale of licences can lead to changes in the nature or location of the good. In such cases, the impact of the transfer of licence will depend on the distribution of consumption patterns. For instance, the impact of allowing a piece of the spectrum to be shifted from cellular telephony to radio broadcasts will depend on the distribution of consumers and their preferences. To take another example, consider a case where the transfer or trade of licences leads to differential impacts, depending on the location over which the restricted good is spread. If one makes emission restrictions tradable, the consequences of such an endeavour will depend on the area of impact. If the emission under consideration is the chemical mercury, which is not degraded or diluted over a long period, the implication of tradability can be quite disastrous, whereas tradable permits may promote efficiency in the case of carbon dioxide emissions. In the former case, the area of impact would be very local and irreversible, while in the latter case the area of impact would be regional, if not global, and the effects may as yet be reversible. 62 India Infrastructure Report 2002 The crucial point that emerges from this discussion is that in designing and implementing optimal regulatory policy, the regulator has to assess distributions of costs and preferences as well as their levels, the structure of the market, and the nature and form of contracts between producers and consumers. Property Rules vs. Liability Rules The state can use property rules under which property rights are guaranteed against non-consensual infringements. Alternatively, the state can use liability rules which discourage misuse of resources by requiring offenders to pay victims for the harm they suffer. The instruments that are used to control pollution provide an example that illustrates the distinction between these rules . Pollution can be controlled through a property rule that imposes a tradable or nontradable4 injunction through appropriate standards on the polluting firm. Alternatively, with a liability rule no standards are set but the firm is liable for damages payable to victims of pollution. The pioneering essay on the issue, ‘The Problem of Social Cost’ (Coase 1960), sets out the analysis of the choice across different rules. In this essay, Coase analyzed situations where the economic activity of an agent has unintended consequences on another, that is, an externality is present. Coase points out that if information is perfect and transaction costs are non-existent it does not matter on whom the law places legal liability or whether property or liability rules are employed—a free bargain can always be worked out with an end result that is characterized by an efficient allocation of resources. The other equally significant point made in this work is that the ‘real world’ is often characterized by the presence of transaction costs, and if transaction costs are admitted then efficiency is sensitive to who bears the legal liability and what rules are used to protect property. In later works, Calabresi and Melamed (1972) and Kaplow and Shavell (1996) have extended the analysis of the choice between property rules and liability rules. In the presence of externalities and no possibilities of bargaining, liability principles do better than property rules. This is because, given that the harm and prevention costs are the private knowledge of the victim and the injurer respectively, liability rules induce flexibility since the injurer will abate the harm as long as the prevention cost is less than the average harm. Property rules on the other hand end up using estimates of costs and harm, which lead to inflexible permissions to pollute/abate with greater error in allocation on the average. Bargaining raises the prospect of reducing the disadvantage faced by property rules as it creates the possibility that parties can trade their rights in mutually beneficial ways. However, in this case the crucial parameter relates to the distribution of costs and harm. In general, the dominance of the liability rule continues, though asymmetric or highly skewed distributions of costs and harm can lead to a preference for property rules. The advantage of the liability rule is clearly related to the ability to correctly assess average harm. If the system (legal, administrative, and procedural) systematically underestimates harm, then the liability principle can do much worse than the property rule. If the problem at hand is such that it involves idiosyncratic valuation of the resource in question where the two parties have different private valuation, then property rules dominate over liability rules. Under a property rule, transfers take place only if the valuation of the owner is less than the valuation of potential takers, and that too through a compensation acceptable to the owner. If liability rules were used in such instances with compensation being based on averages of values, more than optimal level of takings or dispossession will take place.5 Thus, we see that whether we seek to promote effective allocation of the right to use resources through property rules or liability rules depends on the ability of the regulator to assess cost and harm/benefit as well as their distribution over the target population. The above discussion has some important lessons for regulation, since regulators face these choices endemically. To illustrate, if a regulator is called on to make a decision on how to allocate the frequency bandwidth, the regulating agency can use the property rule route by first creating rights in the spectrum, which in turn can be bought from the right holder by future users. Alternatively, the agency can opt for the liability principle and allow people to use the spectrum in an unfettered way, and if their independent action leads to harm or major restrictions/constraints on a potentially expanding service, then the aggrieved party can 5 4 Strictly speaking the case of non-tradable rights do not fit into the dual categorization of property and liability rules. Instead, they belong to the set of rules associated with inalienability, where the court determines who gets an entitlement and the value of the entitlement, but forbids the sale of the entitlement. See Calabresi and Melamed (1972). As we have noted earlier in the discussion of quantitative restrictions, tradability itself depends on the distribution of impact. One should note that the acceptability of compensation is critical to the result. If the compensation is decided by a third party—court, executive branch, or Parliament—and it is not subject to review, then we may find excessive dispossession. It could be argued that one of the key problems in large infrastructure projects where large populations are displaced is that idiosyncratic valuation has been performed inadequately. This problem has been compounded by the restricted and distorted nature of the land market, as pointed out by Morris (2000). The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 63 go to court to seek compensation under the law of torts. To take another example, let us say an agency empowered to regulate telecommunications has to ensure that demand for telephone connections has to be met by a specified period. The agency can fix prices and hope that suppliers will meet the targeted demand or it can specify quantities that suppliers must supply and thereby cover demand. The optimal decision in all these cases depends on an assessment of the distribution of technology, benefits, costs etc. as well as on the ability of the regulator to assess technology and benefits. In addition, the regulator will be required to supervise the implementation of incomplete contracts under imperfect information. Therefore, simply put, the specific and contextual knowledge is paramount in sectors that are characterized by rapidly changing technology, such as telecom. Additionally, while these insights have been worked out as choices of instruments, the nature of information to be processed makes it imperative that the institutions that choose the instruments of regulation, as well as operationalize them, have the right design and governance. GOVERNANCE STRUCTURES: LEGISLATURE, EXECUTIVE, AND JUDICIARY In all the cases discussed above, it can be discerned that in choosing and implementing an efficient instrument the regulator needs to process a variety of different information. Such assessment includes the distribution of benefits and costs from the public utility over the target population, the nature of technology and its distribution over the producers, and the structure and implementation of contracts between producers, resource owners and final consumers. Thus, the regulator must do on a smaller scale what the state is expected to do in aggregate for all public policy. Thus, even though it may not be openly apparent, the problems of regulatory design mirror the concerns of constitutional governance, albeit on a smaller scale. One can take a cue from this and first try to articulate the kind of information that each institution—the legislature, the executive, and the judiciary—is equipped to process. To make decisions that explicitly or implicitly affect the distribution of resources, the legislature, in ideal terms, is structured to capture the preferences of the voting population. The executive, largely organized as a hierarchical system, executes the will of the legislature. To implement this, the executive processes data by drawing upon scientific, epidemiological, and statistical study. The executive can be seen as a hierarchical expert body that makes a number of technical decisions in the face of incomplete information. The judiciary resolves disputes keeping in mind procedural, statutory, and constitutional limitations. Since judicial decisions have to be perforce fair, judicial information is gathered from contesting parties in accordance with the stipulated rules of evidence and procedure. The adjudicating authority sorts out conflicting evidence to come up with a decision, where this decision is made under conditions of asymmetric information. The specialized information processing abilities of each institution is starkly encapsulated in the doctrine of separation of powers. The doctrine of separation of powers can be viewed as a device that encourages transactional efficiency by delegating tasks to institutions in accordance with their ability to process unique categories of information. A heuristic elucidation of this is possible by considering a problem that surrounds the recent decision of the Supreme Court of India requiring all commercial vehicles in Delhi to convert to compressed natural gas (CNG) fuel to lower pollution levels.6 However, this decision has not been without controversy as it appears that mandatory conversion to CNG by all vehicles is not necessarily the most efficient way to bring down emission levels. Other options could have been considered such as changing the composition of diesel or eliminating fuel price distortions that flow from the system of administered prices and so on. The decision on the appropriate technology should have ideally been made by the executive using a body of experts, which would be in a position to take into account all relevant scientific and statistical data, and such decisions need to be flexible to changes in technology and external conditions. Since a court is structured to make an assessment on competing claims, where contesting parties provide relevant information, it is difficult for the court to make such decisions or alter them expeditiously. This case illustrates the point that if the doctrine of separation of powers is violated by one of the institutions breaching its bounds and taking on the task of another, certain social costs will emerge because each institution is built to best process only a certain category of information. The importance of the doctrine of separation of powers, among other things, lies in encouraging transactional efficiency. Admittedly, the analysis of this case is inherently far more complex because the Supreme Court had to take recourse to such extreme action because of endemic executive failure. A similar class of failure can be seen in the widespread and persistent opposition to large infrastructure projects. This opposition arises because the legislature, for a variety of reasons of electoral failure, has not succeeded in giving adequate voice and transparency to the project effected people. In these cases, as well, there is a tendency to turn to the courts for remedy.7 While it is 6 This refers to the interim orders dated 28 July 1998 and 22 September 1998 that have followed from Writ Petition (Civil) No. 13029/1985 put into the Suprme Court by M.C. Mehta. Also see M.C. Mehta vs. Union of India (2000) 9 SCC 519. 7 The recent judicial intervention on the Narmada dam––Narmada Bachao Andolan vs. Union of India (2000) 10 SCC 664––is a case 64 India Infrastructure Report 2002 difficult here to detail all the sources of pervasive executive or legislative failure that characterize Indian governance, the absence of adequate separation of powers in India can contribute to an explanation of persistent executive failure. To pursue this chain of thought in relation to the regulation of infrastructure activity, it may be noted that the doctrine of separation of powers impacts on regulation of infrastructure at two levels. One, regulation is embedded in the wider configuration of separation of powers that characterize the governance structure of a country. Two, the design of regulation itself requires a mix of decisions that fall in the rubric of these different types of institutions. A comparison between the role that the doctrine of separation of powers plays in influencing the design of regulation in the United States of America and in parliamentary democracies provides some interesting insights. In operational terms, the United States of America exhibits the most unadulterated form of separation of powers. As is well known, in the US the three bodies, namely the legislature, the executive, and the judiciary, are distinct from each other. They are elected8 by different constituencies and for different terms of office. In terms of regulation, this can be translated into thinking of the legislature (Congress) as the law making principal that delegates the responsibility of implementing the law to the executive (federal bureaucracy) which acts as an agent (McCubbins, Noll, and Weingast 1987). As is the case with all principal-agent relationships, the answer to the question as to whether the agent will work in the interest of the principal crucially depends on the techniques employed by the principal to monitor and control the agent. There appear to be two techniques whereby the US Congress ensures reasonable compliance by the bureaucracy. One, the Congress directly monitors administrative activity using extensive accounting procedures and has the power to cut out funding to nonperforming agencies. Secondly, rule making by the administration is controlled by an administrative procedure referred to as ‘notice and comment’ rule making. This procedure requires that before rules are announced, the contents of potential rules are described to the public in an accessible language and the views of all interested parties are solicited. In addition to this, the administrative procedure guarantees interested parties the right to participate in the administrative process, and therefore the rules can be subject to judicial review before being formalized. While judicial review can stall the speed with which rules can be in point. In this case the court, in our opinion, quite correctly held for the doctrine of separation of powers. The point is that the court is simply not equipped to assess distributional impacts. 8 The lower levels of the judiciary are in fact locally elected. The senior judiciary is appointed on the recommendation of the executive and approval of the Senate. implemented, this process controls both arbitrary action by the executive and forestalls systemic capture of the executive. Overall, the separation of powers as manifest in the United States of America acts to ensure that the intention of the legislature is put into operation in a transparent manner. In contrast, the separation of powers is much weaker under parliamentary democracies. Under this system, the party or the coalition of parties that wins the maximum number of seats in Parliament forms the government. This government in turn controls the administration through a hierarchical set of commands originating from the governing cabinet. Though ostensibly Parliament is the law maker, it is the cabinet that not only sets much of the agenda of law making but also implements the law. This continuum between the workings of Parliament and the government tends to blur the distinction between the legislature and the executive. Under parliamentary systems, the control of bureaucrats is achieved through informal channels and is therefore not transparent. Typically, in this system courts do not play much of a role in monitoring administrative action, and when approached, largely confine themselves to ensuring that bureaucrats respect statutory guidelines.9 If perchance statutory guidelines are vague, courts tend not to intervene. In this system, if interest groups want to direct rule making, this has to be done by influencing party politicians and civil servants informally and not on the basis of legal guarantees. Since this influence is not transparent, the discretion of politicians/civil servants often determines as to which interest group will prevail. The absence of clear separation of power under parliamentary democracies tends to have an adverse impact on regulation design because administrative procedures lack transparency. It is beyond the scope of the discussion here to enter into a debate on whether India needs to restructure away from a parliamentary form of governance. Instead, the point that has to be realized is that since the doctrine of separation of powers under parliamentary democracies operates weakly, this implies that under parliamentary systems regulatory agencies function in an atmosphere where procedures are not inherently structured to be transparent. This lack of transparency raises the onus on the regulatory agency to implement devices to promote voice and equity decisions. 9 For example the Supreme Court has held that ‘The executive, in running the administration of the country, should not be cowed down and should be allowed to have full confidence in its own existence so that its decision-making process is not, in any way, affected. . . . If they were constantly under the fear or threat of being proceeded against in a court of law for even the slightest of lapse or under constant fear of exemplary damages being awarded against them, they will develop a defensive attitude which would not be in the interest of administration.’ Common Cause, A Registered Society vs. Union of India (1999) 6 SCC 667. The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 65 The nature of the problem can be illustrated by invoking the case of one of the centrepieces of regulation in postliberalization India––Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI)10. In the face of radical technological changes in telecommunications over the last 15 years, Indian policy makers have been pressured into allowing private participation into the sector. In this process, TRAI was set up as a regulatory body, structured to perform both executive and judicial functions. Perusing through the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India Act, it becomes evident that the Authority possesses limited executive powers. In Chapter III of the Act, which enumerates the powers and functions of the Authority, Section 11(1)(a) lists the areas over which the Authority has recommendatory powers. These include recommendations on when new entrants should be invited, the terms and conditions of licences, revocation of licences for noncompliance of terms and conditions, and efficient management of available spectrum. In addition to this, the Authority is supposed to recommend measures to encourage competition, efficiency, and technological change. In the same breath, in Section 11(d) of the Act it is explicitly stated that while the central government might seek recommendations from the Authority, to quote from the Act ‘the recommendations of the Authority specified in the clause (a) of this sub-section shall not be binding upon the central government’. In Section 11(b) the ‘functions’ of the Authority are listed, which include ensuring that terms and conditions of licences are complied with, technical coordination across providers is maintained, quality of services is controlled, and revenue sharing among providers is monitored. Next, in Section 11(c), the Authority is given fiat to levy fees and other charges which have been decided as a part of the regulatory endeavour. From this description of the powers and functions of the Authority, it is evident that key decisions associated with entry, licensing, and distribution of the spectrum frequency lie with the government, while the TRAI maintains residual command over co-ordinating certain practices. In this context, it is ironical that the TRAI Act should state in clause 11(4) that ‘The Authority shall ensure transparency while exercising its powers and discharging its functions’, while there is no device to ensure that the decisions of the Central government are transparent. It has been periodically pointed out that notwithstanding the presence of TRAI, important decisions on the telecom sector have originated from the Prime Minister’s Office. (Jain 2001). The TRAI, in its role as the Telecom Disputes Settlement and Appellate Tribunal, also functions as a court that deals with disputes that may arise between the licencor and 10 This structure has served as a model for a number of subsequent regulatory institutions. licencee, between service providers and groups of consumers. In addition to this, the Tribunal can also hear appeals against decisions made by the TRAI. The Act grants these possibilities, as long as the dispute does not come under the purview of either the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices (MRTP) Act, the Consumer Protection Act, or the Indian Telegraph Act. This clearly implies that while the Tribunal might contain some skirmishes, the solution to substantial issues surrounding the mitigation of risk and the guarantee of rights have to be worked out either in other courts or in the labyrinths of the concerned Ministries. It has now become standard practice in India when constructing regulatory institutions to include a wing that acts as a court. Ostensibly, this is a part of a general trend, that is encouraged because the civil courts are so overwhelmingly clogged that it is felt that special courts/ tribunals will speed up the required justice. Thus for example, Sections 33(1) and (2) of the Gujarat Gas (Regulation of Transmission, Supply and Distribution) Act 2001 seeks to exclude jurisdiction of all civil courts from matters in this area.11 This fragmentation of the court system might ‘speed up’ some cases, but surely lead to inefficiencies that are generated by ambiguous jurisdictions. The key problem with such fragmentation is that it inhibits the development of unified legal doctrines, for instance in the important area of contract law.12 It has been suggested that even though Britain follows a parliamentary scheme of governance, the success of some of her endeavours to privatize infrastructure activities can be attributed to a well developed system of contract law (Spiller and Vogelsang 1996). A well developed contract law, even in the presence of opaque administrative action and absence of formal mechanisms to capture different voices, can restrain regulatory discretion and provide private investors with adequate assurances against opportunistic behaviour. Keeping this kind of view in mind, the most expeditious way of constructing good governance in India might be to reform the legal system such that it upholds the basic common law tradition of enforcing contracts. 11 There is a tendency in such legislation to seek to exclude the jurisdiction of not only the lower courts but also that of the senior judiciary as well. The Supreme Court in the L. Chandra Kumar case ((1997) 3 SCC 261) has stipulated the structure and role of independent tribunals. 12 In this connection, it is useful to point out the approach followed by the Report of the Advisory Group on Bankruptcy Law (RBI 2001). The committee eschewed the temptation to set up an independent tribunal and instead opted to recommend a special bench of the high court to deal with these matters. To enhance efficiency, it was suggested that this bench be equipped with its own distinct procedural requirements, as well as a special executive arm through the notion of a bankruptcy trustee. The trustee will bring the necessary technical and managerial skill to implement an effective restructuring or liquidation package. 66 India Infrastructure Report 2002 As is evident from the TRAI example, regulation of infrastructure activity is problematic because governance structures force the difficulties of over-and under-delegation onto the regulatory process. The regulatory agency faces under-delegation because it possesses only the weak power of suggesting recommendations on key issues––new entrants, licences, and distribution of the frequency spectrum. Concomitantly, these central issues are also in the purview of the executive branch of the government, which makes these decisions in a non-transparent manner. The agency is also burdened with simultaneous over-delegation in its capacity as a judicial body. The system over-delegates by breaking up the court system, and prevents unified principles of contract from emerging. Further, there is a persistent uneasiness in the air, since such delegation conflicts even with the limited separation of powers guaranteed by the Constitution and is open to judicial challenges. If indeed the governance structure can be described in this manner, this has had a negative consequence on the ability of a liberalized economy to deliver in India. It can be concluded that at least three changes in orientation are required to usher in effective regulation. First, it is essential that the regulator either directly or indirectly provides for effective voice and equity in its decision making processes. Two, it is also important that the regulatory process provide for adequate protection of rights through a transparent process of judicial review. Finally, it is imperative to encompass an efficient process for executive decisionmaking through a set of incentive compatible hierarchies. To do this correctly will require us to be sensitive to the delegation of powers under the Constitution and seek to rectify institutional failures in the basic constitutional institutions through a promotion of transparency and voice. 4.2 HOW PUBLIC FEEDBACK AIDS PUBLIC ACCOUNTABILITY Samuel Paul • Gopakumar K. THE DISABLING ENVIRONMENT SERVICES OF PUBLIC During 1996–7 central and state governments together spent about Rs 3655 or 25 per cent of per capita income, on providing public services (World Bank 1997); yet, most of the available information on these services is generally limited to expenditures incurred and gross measures of outcomes such as literacy, production, and other physical indicators. Beyond this information, from formal sources we know little about the quality of services provided by the state. And whatever little is known paints a disturbing picture. To quote some figures, 60 per cent of families in India do not have electricity at home; 40 per cent of Indians do not have access to water at home; 53 per cent of children in India suffer from malnutrition; 84 per cent of the population have no access to sanitation, and 58 per cent of primary schools have no safe drinking water (India Today 2000). And even where these facilities exist, their quality could be very poor. Most people hold government responsible for this dismal state of public services. The utter callousness and lack of accountability rampant in many public offices raises the question: why are leaders in government unable to cleanse the system? Indeed, there are many things that a government can and should do to improve matters. But for a variety of reasons discussed below, government service providers continue to be unresponsive to, and often uninterested in, the needs and problems of the public. The Context of Public Service Delivery13 The state in India has traditionally been dominant in the area of public services, and is often its sole provider. The downside of this ‘monopoly power’ is that users of most public services do not have the option to ‘exit’ from the government supplier to another supplier. It also creates a pronounced tendency on the part of the service providers to withhold information from the customers and users, thereby making it difficult for them to demand accountability. Secondly, the absence of market competition has not been compensated for by any other institutional mechanism to ensure efficient service delivery. Traditional mechanisms, such as public audit of government expenditure and legislative oversight, focus only on a review of inputs. Expenditures are audited to see whether proper procedures and norms have been adhered to. While this is an aspect of accountability, it does not tell us anything about how well the money was spent. This is because very little attention is (or can be) given to the outputs and outcomes of the inputs. The problem is exacerbated by the difficulties in measuring outputs and in monitoring field level activities. Legislative oversight gets blunted by the vastness of the scope of services and the lack of information available to the legislators. More 13 This section draws upon ideas articulated in a forthcoming book by Samuel Paul, Holding the State to Account: Report Cards for Responsive Governance. The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 67 disturbing is the collusion between service providers and those responsible for monitoring their performance. The internal working and decision making of public agencies cannot easily be monitored or even observed by those outside the system. The scope for the pursuit of parochial and selfserving interests and for corruption is considerable. Thirdly, citizens are seldom able to engage in sustained collective action to demand increased public accountability. There is an implicit assumption that once people elect a government, it is for the latter to enforce accountability on all service providers. Perhaps, an even more important reason for this attitude of citizens is that their motivation to engage in collective action is usually weak. The fact that the severity of problems concerning public services that people face generally tends to vary from day to day and from household to household implies that sustaining collective action is difficult, even when a group is able to initiate action at some point in time. Moreover, some people may not invest time and energy for collective action, as they feel they could get a ‘free ride’ from the success of the efforts of others in any case. This is a major reason why the incentives for collective action are weak, except in certain critical situations. This is a general problem with collective action. Fourthly, the legal framework of the country can be a barrier to improved public accountability. Administrators typically try to work within the framework of the laws and regulations of their organizations. Accounts get audited because a law requires them to do so. Investments are made according to the laws and regulations governing the organization. If the law is silent on the standards and other attributes of services, as it is in India, provider agencies are likely to pay less attention to them.14 Why are improvements in public service and ensuring accountability to consumers and citizens not priorities of those in power, despite the latter’s claims to the contrary? A good place to start is with the planning function in the government of India. These are the focal points for where the objectives of development, and resource allocation and management, are articulated and decided. However, the real problem is that the planners’ influence, if any, is only on investments, and not necessarily on outputs. The government has typically seen its task to lie in mobilizing resources for investment. Rakesh Mohan (2000) has summed up the situation well: ‘The existing planning system has essentially resulted in the central government acting as a giant financial intermediary, borrowing from the public in different ways to finance plan expenditure at both the central and state levels. In this system there is no connection between the viability of projects and their financing costs. The consequence has been that returns from these investments have been consistently low’. 14 In the United States and the United Kingdom, the law itself lays down the standards for electricity supply. A Way Out of the Impasse? Could the market have done a better job of producing and delivering public services than the state? Champions of privatization will certainly answer this question in the affirmative. After all, privatization has worked well in many developing and developed countries. However, privatization does not mean that government has nothing to do with these services. It will be necessary for government and its specialized regulatory agencies to specify the standards and conditions of the services, regulate tariffs and related financial matters, and monitor the service providers’ performance. As India undergoes privatization, if functions such as standard setting, pricing, and supervision are not well-designed by the state, ‘reforms’ may result in the creation of a new set of private sector monopolies whose performance is even worse than that of the public sector. With the right kind of initiatives from the government, however, the scope for improvement is large. More importantly, some services would necessarily have to be provided by the state—law and order, for example. Similarly, basic education, preventive health, maintenance of certain common facilities, pollution control, etc. are not tasks that can be left wholly to market forces. At a minimum, the government has to play a regulatory role and monitor standards in these services. Getting the government to deliver these services more responsively to the people will be a continuing challenge in any society. While the role of the market has been discussed a great deal, that of civil society as a force for ensuring better services has received little attention. Civil society institutions have played an important role in mobilizing public opinion in the reform, the state, and its institutions in ex-Soviet countries, South Africa, and Eastern Europe. Civil society here refers not only to formal entities like the media or professional associations, but also to the informal networks of people from different walks of life. Powerful movements involving civil society have surfaced in response to major crises of governance in several countries. The ‘people power’ revolutions of the Philippines that led to the overthrow of two corrupt presidents are an inspiring example. Similar civil society movements in Indonesia and Iran also achieved significant results. Organized sections of society such as labour and industry associations have always exerted pressure for or against major policies. But on the issue of public services there is no natural organization of citizens. They are after all the primary stakeholders. Yet it is citizens and their groups who can and should have exercised the pressure on government. But their ‘voice’ is seldom well-orchestrated or heard. Occasional protests in times of crisis are usually not sustained. 68 India Infrastructure Report 2002 One promising approach is for the public to give their assessment of services to the public agencies concerned and act as watchdogs in the process. Campaigns and dialogues would be more purposive and meaningful when people are armed with information that is well focused and pertinent to a given situation. Civil society institutions can potentially play an active role in assembling and using such information to stimulate public agencies to improve their services, and also in drawing people together. EXPLORING THE POTENCY REPORT CARDS OF ‘VOICE’ THROUGH What are the practical ways to use ‘voice and participation’ to change the highly disabling ambience of public service delivery? (Paul 1998) When competition is absent, as in the case of most public goods, popular voice can reduce information asymmetries, which can challenge service providers to perform better and lower transaction costs (Paul 1995a). When low incentives and weak monitoring combine to produce inefficient public services, voice mechanisms can inform public officials of the problems and act as a kind of pressure for improvements (Dreze and Sen 1999). Report Cards on Public Utilities, pioneered by Public Affairs Centre (PAC)—a non-profit society based in Bangalore, India— is now widely recognized as a powerful voice mechanism. It builds on the notion that feedback has a value to both the actor and the affected. ‘Report Cards’ provide a simple and widely replicable tool for improving transparency and public accountability. Report Cards compiled from citizens’ responses to structured queries can objectively assess both qualitative and quantitative dimensions of various public services. This Report Card can be used to stimulate collective action by citizens and provide leaders with an opportunity to design reforms and bring in a strategic reorientation (Paul 1998). Experiences with Report Cards, both national and international, have amply demonstrated their potential for demanding more public accountability and providing a credible database to facilitate proactive civil society responses. What are Report Cards? The Report Card methodology presents a simple but highly flexible approach for organizing public feedback (Gopakumar 1997). This methodology can be used to: • Generate citizen feedback on the degree of satisfaction with the services provided. • Catalyze citizens to adopt proactive stances by demanding more accountability, accessibility, and responsiveness from the service providers. • Serve as a diagnostic tool for service providers, external consultants, and analysts/researchers to facilitate effective prognosis and therapy. • Encourage public agencies to adopt and promote citizen friendly practices, design performance standards, and facilitate transparency in operations. Stages in a Report Card Survey15 • • • • • • • Identifying issues through focus group discussions. Designing the instruments of survey. Identifying the sample for the survey. Conducting the survey by an independent agency. Collecting qualitative data. Placing the results in the public domain. Conducting advocacy and establishing partnerships. PAC’s Report Cards were first applied in the urban services sector. But the approach is equally relevant in many other infrastructure sectors. EVALUATING AND BENCHMARKING CIVIL SERVICES IN BANGALORE The First Report Card Study of public services in Bangalore (1993) involved a random sample survey of city households (Paul 1995b). The residential areas of the city were stratified by the age of the locality, and six areas were picked at random from among the old and established, the new, and the intermediate areas. Within each area, sample households were selected, using random numbers. Care was taken to include households across income groups. Samples were sufficiently large to give reliable results. Questionnaires were administered to the selected households, provided they had an interaction with one or more public agencies in the preceding six months. The survey attempts to cover three key questions. How much does it cost the user to avail the services? What are the costs borne by a non-user in having to do without it? What is the level of satisfaction with specific dimensions/ features of the service? A seven-point scale suitably validated is used to score the degree of satisfaction. Poor Scores of Public Services The overall satisfaction with public agencies (general households) is shown in Table 4.2.1 in which, ‘satisfied’ refers to a rating of six and seven and ‘dissatisfied’ refers to one and two. In between is a ‘zone of ambivalence’, which indicates that the respondent is not clear on his/her preferences. The table shows that none of the eight service 15 See Upp (1995). The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 69 Table 4.2.1 Overall Satisfaction with Public Agencies in Bangalore (General Households), 1993 Agency/Service Telephones Municipal Corporation Electricity Water Health Regional Transport Office Development Authority Public sector Banks Average rating Percentage of users satisfied 3.6 2.9 3.5 3.0 4.3 3.5 2.5 4.0 Percentage of users dissatisfied 9 5 6 4 25 1 1 20 28 49 31 46 19 36 65 26 (*Higher is better) providers in Bangalore receives a satisfactory score from the respondents. Even the best average scores indicated (hospitals, 4.3; banks, 4.0) do not go beyond the zone of ambivalence, that is, 3.0–5.0. Second, only one out of 100 respondents in Bangalore considers the Bangalore Development Agency’s (BDA) services as satisfactory. Only four, five, and six persons out of 100 think that Bangalore Water and Sewerage Services Board (BWSSB), Bangalore Metropolitan Corporation (BMC), and Karnataka Electricity Board (KEB), respectively, are performing satisfactorily. The study also highlighted the phenomenon of corruption (see Table 4.2.2). Taking all transactions with all eight services, 14 per cent of the respondents in Bangalore paid speed money (a euphemism for bribes) to the staff, either directly or through agents. There is evidence of a higher concentration of speed money in some agencies than in others. Thus, every third person dealing with the BDA and Regional Transport Office (RTO) and every fourth person dealing with the BMC paid bribes. Respondents also reported that in 50 per cent of the cases, officials demanded bribes, thereby emphasizing the extortionary nature of corruption. The findings of the study elicited wide interest. A leading daily, the Times of India, started a weekly feature with a graphic depiction of each one of the findings over a period. The feature continued for about two months, bringing the concept of Report Cards to the public attention. Though the responses from most agency heads and senior government officials were lukewarm, the BDA, which was rated the worst across all qualitative and quantitative dimensions of service delivery, responded with a request for a follow-up survey. This resulted in a unique collaboration wherein a public service agency requested an external research group to provide assistance in getting feedback on various dimensions of service delivery. The second study sought to address some pertinent questions. Are the customers of BDA satisfied with the quality of service? Is the phenomenon of corruption as rampant as was brought out by the first Report Card? What are the perceptible areas of weakness in the functioning of the BDA? Would the public be willing to participate in the process of improving the BDA’s services? To better understand the situation, the functional constraints experienced by the officials of BDA were also assessed through interactive discussions. Following the study, a series of training programmes were organized for the staff of the BDA. Table 4.2.2 Bribes Paid to Various Agencies in Bangalore, 1993 Agency/Service Electricity Board Water Board City Corporation Hospitals Regional Transport Office Telephones Development Authority Average Proportion in sample claiming to have paid a bribe (per cent) 11 12 21 17 33 4 33 14 Average payment per transaction (Rs) 206 275 656 396 648 110 1850 857 70 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Table 4.2.3 Satisfaction of Users in Interactions with Public Agencies/Service Providers in Bangalore Service Per cent satisfied Bangalore Water Supply and Sewerage Board Karnataka Electricity Board Municipal Corporation Bangalore Telephones Regional Transport Office Public Hospitals Bangalore Development Authority Per cent dissatisfied 1994 1999 4 6 5 9 14 25 1 10 13 25 30 18 30 8 The most important gain of the survey and the intervention that followed was the public awareness created by the Report Card on the need for active citizen participation in order to improve the quality of civic services. At the time the Report Card was undertaken, very few active residents’ groups existed in Bangalore. Today, there are over one hundred such groups who are networked with shared activities among them (Paul 1998: p 14). Apart from bringing out the levels of satisfaction or dissatisfaction with the services, other aspects like staff behaviour, incidence of problems and resolution were covered. Most importantly, the study ‘measured’ something as abstract as ‘corruption’. The additional problems of the urban poor could also be brought out. After a gap of more than five years, a second Report Card on the public services of Bangalore was prepared by PAC in 1999 (Paul and Sekhar 1999). The main objective of this exercise was to assess whether the services had improved or worsened over this period and in what respects. Table 4.2.3 brings out the changes over the five years. Table 4.2.4 similarly brings out the aspect of bribery in the two years of the surveys. Table 4.2.3 shows that during the five-year period, satisfaction has increased across the board. The BDA and 1994 1999 46 31 49 28 36 19 65 31 38 26 11 26 11 47 the RTO though are perhaps the two exceptions where there has been little change. Table 4.2.4 brings to light some intriguing findings. Alongside an increase in satisfaction, there has been a concomitant rise in incidences of corruption in all agencies, with the exception of the BWSSB, Karnataka Power Transmission Corporation Ltd. or KPTCL, and the BDA. Even more disheartening is the fact that the average amount paid as bribes has gone up dramatically (significantly more than the consumer price index) in four out of 10 agencies. DEVELOPING WARD BASED INDICATORS MUMBAI IN Mumbai is estimated to have a population of about 13 million, of which about 5.5 million live in slums. To assess the spread and impact of critical public services in the slum areas, PAC in collaboration with the Rationing Kruti Samiti (RKS)—an umbrella organization of 38 non-governmental organizations (NGOs) and grassroot organizations in Mumbai—organized a Report Card Study in 1998 (Balakrishnan and Sekhar 1998). The study probed two pertinent themes: (1) The overall availability, usage, and satisfaction/dissatisfaction with public services; (2) In-depth Table 4.2.4 Bribes Paid to Various Agencies in Bangalore, 1994 and 1999 Agency Bangalore Water Supply and Sewerage Board Karnataka Electricity Board Municipal Corporation Telephones Regional Transport Office Public Hospitals Bangalore Development Authority Proportion in sample claiming to have paid a bribe (per cent) Average payment per transaction in (Rs) 1994 1999 1994 1999 12 11 21 4 33 17 33 35 18 52 26 57 43 78 275 206 656 110 648 396 1850 584 929 3759 245 637 500 7690 The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 71 Table 4.2.5 Availability, Usage and Satisfaction with Public Services in Mumbai, (per cent), 1998 Public Services Public Toilets Drinking Water Garbage Clearance Domestic Lighting Ration Shops High School Health Services Availability Usage Satisfied Dissatisfied 92 97 85 97 99 98 96 92 97 84 97 97 96 96 21 59 50 86 32 91 92 73 38 37 10 66 05 08 Note: Numbers are percent of surveyed. study of problems with services where high levels of dissatisfaction was experienced, with a view to overcome these. The salient findings are summarized in Tables 4.2.5 and 4.2.6. Contrary to popular belief, the problem here is not generally inadequate availability of services. Table 4.2.5 shows that civic facilities are available and much used. What matters are the other factors brought out in Table 4.2.6. Based on the findings generated by the study, a one-day workshop on Developing Partnerships for Action towards a Better Mumbai was organized by PAC and RKS with over 60 participants, including concerned officials from the Municipal Corporation of Greater Mumbai, the Department of Civil Supplies and the Police, representatives of NGOs and community-based organizations or CBOs, and the Press. A major achievement of this meeting was the interest expressed by local government authorities to explore the possibility of citizen–state interactive forums to address local governance issues. The meeting also suggested that on a pilot scale, intervention ought to be planned immediately in a selected ward to improve the interface between local officials and citizens groups for better management of the ward. Accordingly, a project called Watch Your Ward Program (WARP) was initiated in 10 wards in Mumbai. Voluntary associations in these wards carried out the survey and the process of drawing up the results is on. A local NGO, Apnalaya, was involved in this programme. BUSINESS ENVIRONMENT IN KARNATAKA According to the government of Karnataka, 104 large-scale industrial investment proposals worth a total of over Rs. 68,000 crores and 1014 medium-scale projects with a proposed investment of Rs. 9600 crores have come to the state during the eight-year period 1991–8. However, an Table 4.2.6 Reasons for Dissatisfaction among Urban Poor in Mumbai with regard to Certain Services, 1998 Agency/Service Reasons for dissatisfaction (per cent of Urban Poor) Ration Shops • • • • • Poor quality of service (82 per cent) Insufficiency of allotted quantity (95 per cent) Poor quality of the product (92 per cent) Long waiting time (average of 3 hours per visit) Non availability of required commodities (88 per cent) Drinking Water • • • • • Distance to the tap (average of 70 meters) Inadequate quantity (82 per cent) Waiting time was almost 2 hrs on average Frequent failure of water supply (65 per cent) Bad quality of water (33 per cent) Public Toilets • • • • Lack of water in toilets (11 per cent reported water available!) Long wait in queues Long distance to toilets (average distance is 100 meters) Needed alternative arrangements (56 per cent of the time) Garbage Clearance • • • Distance to the disposal spot (average of 50 meters) Inadequacy space for garbage disposal (90 per cent of responses) Irregular clearance (no clearance over a week in 22 per cent of areas) 72 India Infrastructure Report 2002 independent assessment carried out by PAC in June 2000 showed that the actual implementation rates are abysmally low. Only 5 per cent of the large-scale project proposals and 38 per cent of the medium-scale proposals have been implemented. An exploratory survey revealed an interesting spectrum of disabling factors (Paul et al. 2000). Almost 60 per cent of the investors in the large-scale sector identified corruption as the most disabling factor in Karnataka. Four out of 10 respondents have given a similar negative rating to the state of infrastructure. In contrast, only three out of 10 respondents have expressed intense dissatisfaction with taxation and the government–investor interface (see Table 4.2.7). Similarly, medium-scale investors cited corruption, power, roads, and their interface with government as debilitating factors. CREATING PUBLIC AWARENESS The media has played a major role in creating awareness and sensitizing the public. The Report Card findings are generally publicized prominently by major newspapers. Agency specific findings and the novelty of the method used were in part responsible for this response. And, of course, news about corruption always makes good copy. Seminars and meetings are also organized in connection with the release of Report Card findings. Typically, these involve local activists in civic affairs, representatives of residents’ associations, and NGOs interested in the problems of the urban poor. The second Report Card for Bangalore was presented at a public meeting in which the CEOs of major public agencies participated and spoke about the various proposed reform measures. STIMULATING AGENCY REFORMS Report Card studies brought to light a wide panoply of issues, both quantitative and qualitative, and sent strong signals to public service providers. The use of a rating scale permitted the respondents to quantify the extent of their Table 4.2.7 Ranking of Disabling Factors in Karnataka’s Industrial Environment (as expressed by large scale investors) Rating1 Factor Corruption Infrastructure Taxation Interface with Government 3.54 3.20 3.03 2.64 Roads Water Power Telecommunications Taxation Interactions with Government Corruption Manpower Availability Per cent dissatisfied 50.7 44.0 68.0 29.3 49.3 53.3 65.3 21.3 58 41 33 20 per per per per cent cent cent cent Note: 1 Respondents were asked to evaluate the above factors on a scale of 1–5 where 1 was the best and 5 the worst. Ratings indicate average of the scores of all respondents. 2 Proportion of respondents giving 4 or 5 to a factor on the scale satisfaction or dissatisfaction with the service of an agency. The scale was used not only for an overall assessment of an agency, but also for different dimensions of its service. The inter-agency comparisons with respect to public satisfaction and corruption that a Report Card permits also created a platform to stimulate agency interest in addressing the underlying problems. Quantification and rankings demand attention in a way that anecdotes do not. They focus attention on specific agencies and services, that can be embarrassing to those in charge, especially because of the adverse publicity involved. STRENGTHENING CIVIL SOCIETY INITIATIVES The findings and information provided by Report Cards have largely succeeded in catalyzing citizens to take proactive and creative steps. More citizens are involved today as active partners and participants. The Swabhimana Initiative in Bangalore, launched in the wake of the release of the Report Card findings, is one such example. The Initiative, mooted by the then Commissioner of Bangalore City Corporation, is a unique state–citizen forum to improve the quality of civic life in the city. This forum not only experiments with Table 4.2.8 Satisfaction of Medium Scale Investors in Karnataka, 1999 Environmental Factor Intensity of dissatisfaction2 Per cent satisfied 46.7 46.7 18.7 61.3 18.7 30.7 6.7 72.0 The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 73 Box 4.2.1 Making an Informed Choice The Public Affairs Centre’s benchmark survey of the industrial environment in Karnataka in 2000 has been acknowledged as a key input in bringing about drastic reform measures by the government in the form of the Karnataka Industries [Simplification of Procedures and Documentation] Act/Rule-2001. Building on to the findings revealed by the survey on the interface with the various agencies, the new Act has amended many outdated rules and regulations that existed as major inhibiting factors. In a unique experiment of its kind, citizens’ groups in Bangalore collected a set of crucial information from the candidates st anding for elections and then disseminated the comparative database widely to enable voters to make an informed choice. Data collected included candidates’ age, educational qualifications, occupation, value of assets, criminal records (if any), compliance with o ther legal obligations, and priorities for the ward. This exercise was conducted jointly by PAC and Swabhimana. CITIZENS’ MONITORING OF ROAD WORKS To enable interested groups and individuals to monitor the quality of roads, PAC in association with the Department of Science & Technology, government of Karnataka has brought out a ‘Citizens’ Guide on Monitoring the Quality of Road Works’. This ready reckoner charts out easy and inexpensive procedures and methods to effectively monitor the quality of roads. An interesting outcome of this has been a Report Card on the roads in Bangalore, based on the Citizens’ Guide, prepared by students in the age group 12–14 years1. Some of its findings are as follows: On an average, on a 300 metre stretch of footpath, pedestrians have to negotiate 73 obstructions, including illegal encroachments and parked vehicles; 65 per cent of the roads had potholes, 61 per cent of the roads had developed cracks, and 65 per cent were uneven. The findings were then presented to the Commissioner of the city corporation. 1Times of India (2001), ‘Who says the juniors aren’t interested?’, Bangalore, 15 July. new approaches to solving problems, but also disseminates information widely and performs a watchdog function. Most of the Report Card studies conducted in various cities by PAC have been done in close association with public interest groups and NGOs. For these organizations, the methodology has provided a strong, coherent, and credible database, highlighting areas of concern that help them to strategize their options and sharpen their skills in advocacy. In Chennai, The Catalyst Trust, a not-for-profit society, collaborated with PAC in conducting a Citizens’ Audit of Public Services in Rural Tamil Nadu; this exercise benchmarked the impact of charters and policy statements on three critical civic services. DEMOCRATIC RESPONSIVENESS Report Cards draw attention to a plethora of qualitative dimensions like satisfaction, expectation on quality and the like, which are missing from the usual statistics on service delivery. Report Cards may also stimulate political responsiveness: Democracy is not just about elections, but also about what happens in between them. In Bangalore, the Chief Minister’s programme of monitoring public agencies in the city though an innovative forum called ‘Bangalore Agenda Task Force’ uses Report Cards repeatedly to assess the progress of proposed reforms and activities. Findings from these exercises are presented to the city mayor and other elected functionaries and also widely disseminated through the media. CRITICAL SUCCESS FACTORS The factors that facilitate successful use of the methodology are: • Felt need for an objective and credible information: All effective advocacy interventions have been launched from a need to have a credible database. Most partner organizations need the strength of numbers to make their voice more focused and amplified. • Focus on institutions: Report Cards chart out feedback on services and not on individuals. The emphasis is on creating neutral and scientific institutional databases on organizations and their activities, and to pave the way for systemic reforms, and not ‘band-aid solutions’ like transfer of CEOs of poorly rated agencies. This helps to make advocacy less confrontational. • Presence of a local champion: Perhaps the most critical requirement is the need for local stakeholders like NGOs and citizen groups who will own the database, contextualize the findings, and strategize local advocacy actions. • Emphasis on experiential and not perceptional data: Report Cards are not opinion polls. They represent codified experiences of users of services. This ‘user’ dimension gives the findings more weight and credibility. • Conducted by independent and professionally competent group: The credibility of the local champion has to be impeccable for the results to be treated seriously. 74 India Infrastructure Report 2002 CONCLUSION There is a growing awareness among decision makers in government, academia, and advocacy groups on the potential of public feedback for influencing the policy environment and also creating empowering initiatives to make the state more responsive and accountable. In the public sector today, there is a slow but definite shift in focus to the consumer and citizen. The involvement of the civil society is a necessary corollary. What this means is that results on the ground and sustainability are now the acid tests of public investments and state performance. Accessibility, effectiveness, and responsiveness have become the key dimensions of performance of public organizations. Public feedback therefore becomes a powerful instrument to ensure public accountability. Experiments with Report Cards confirm the value of this public feedback mechanism, both to enable citizens to signal service providers about their performance and to stimulate the latter to respond to these signals. The experiences also reinforce the case for benchmarking qualitative and quantitative dimensions over time. The use of public feedback can act as a proxy for the pressure of competition in a context where customers have few choices. Report Cards also provide strong signals to service providers to institutionalize the concept of public feedback as part of their monitoring functions. 4.3 THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK FOR PRIVATE PARTICIPATION Piyush Joshi • R.V. Anuradha Law is the basic instrument that defines rights and obligations. The legal framework governing a particular infrastructure sector would, therefore, determine the extent and feasibility of private participation of facilities in that particular sector. The term ‘legal framework’, for the purposes of this paper means the statutes, rules, regulations, and administrative orders governing a particular infrastructure sector. Besides defining the feasibility, the legal framework also affects the economic viability of private participation in an infrastructure project. In fact, in no other activity is the close interaction between law and economics so evident and clear as it is in relation to private participation in infrastructure projects. The legal framework is also the primary source of risk distribution in infrastructure projects. It provides the basic framework within which the parties determine the manner in which the various risks associated with a project are distributed, managed, and mitigated. CONSTITUTIONAL PROVISIONS The Constitutional framework in India does not permit for a single law governing grant of rights for development of projects in all the various infrastructure sectors. The Seventh Schedule to the Constitution of India distributes legislative jurisdiction over infrastructure sectors between the Union and the state.16 Further, the executive powers of the Union 16 The Constitution of India, vide Chapter I of Part XI, and in particular Article 246 read with the Seventh Schedule, specifies the manner of distribution of the legislative powers over various subjects including infrastructure sectors and taxation. For a more detailed discussion on this aspect, see Joshi, (2001). executive extend to the matters with respect to which the Union Parliament has powers to make laws and similarly the executive powers of the state executive extend to the matters with respect to which the concerned state legislature has powers to make laws.17 Though presence of sector specific laws supporting private participation in a given infrastructure sector provide a more secure basis for private participation, the absence of a sector specific law per se does not preclude the possibility of private participation in the particular sector. If the relevant legislative body has not enacted a law governing a particular sector that is within its jurisdiction, as defined by the Seventh Schedule of the Constitution, then the corresponding executive authority may allow for private participation in such a sector. Private participation based solely on the exercise of executive authority is, however, exposed to a greater degree of political and legal risk since an exercise of executive authority is always subject to a subsequent exercise of legislative authority. It also carries a higher risk of being challenged in the courts of law as being an unguided, arbitrary, and unreasonable exercise of discretion. Issues related to the extent of executive authority may also be raised. If such executive power is exercised, then it is best done through formulation of a clear policy framework for the sectors in which private participation is being allowed. A good example of an infrastructure sector not having a specific law governing it is water supply and sewage treatment. The power to regulate ‘water supply’ is vested with the state legislature. The exceptions to the jurisdiction 17 See Articles 73 and 162, Constitution of India. The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 75 of the state legislature, under the Constitution of India, in relation to ‘water supply’ are: (i) regulation of development of interstate rivers to the extent such control of development has been declared by law to vest with the Union; (ii) law relating to adjudication of disputes relating to interstate rivers and; (iii) territorial waters. A number of states do not have a specific law regulating water supply for domestic and industrial use. Usually water supply within a municipal area is governed by the law of that particular state regulating the formation, powers, and functions of the municipal bodies within the state. If however, a water supply project is established in an area outside the jurisdiction of the municipal bodies, then no specific law would be governing it. In such circumstances, the executive power of the state can be exercised to formulate policies, guidelines, and framework regulating such projects. Executive power can be exercised to formulate clear policies and guidelines even in the presence of specific legislation as long as it is within the framework provided by the law. The two National Telecom Policies (the National Telecom Policy, 1994 and the New Telecom Policy, 1999) are examples of exercise of executive power to provide for the basis for the grant of licences, under the Telegraph Act, 1885, to private entities for providing various telecom services. ESSENTIAL FEATURES OF THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK Apart from the statutory framework governing private participation discussed above, the contractual documentation for any project is another aspect that would constitute the ‘legal framework’ governing a particular project. The statutory framework generally governs a particular sector, and is very rarely project specific. Its aim is usually to establish a suitable basis for the project specific contractual framework to be established. Statutory framework comprises of the laws, rules, regulations, order etc. enacted by the relevant authorities, whereas the contractual framework comprises of the project specific contracts entered among the participants within the framework formulated by the statutory framework. The contractual framework will reflect the negotiated and agreed upon basis of controlling the interests of the various participants. The following sections shall briefly analyse the key features of the statutory and contractual framework that can facilitate private participation. Comprehensiveness of Rights Whatever be the structure for private participation that is adopted in relation to a particular infrastructure sector, it would be imperative that all the rights required by the private participant to implement the project within the framework of the given structure be granted to the private participant. For example, in the case of BOOT (Build, Own, Operate and Transfer) some of the critical rights that need to be vested with the private developer are: • Right to enable it to develop, design, construct, own, operate, manage, and maintain the infrastructure facility. • Right to enable it to commercially utilize the infrastructure facility, including the right to determine, collect, retain, and appropriate tariff from the users of the facility. • Right to enable it to restrict access to the facility or suspend the supply of service (as the case may be) to defaulters. • Right to enable it to create an enforceable and valid security interest in favour of the lenders over assets and revenue streams. Certainty and Continuity Certainty of the rights vested and of the legal framework governing the project leads to greater comfort relating to the scope of the private participation and enforcement of rights in relation thereto. The continuity of the very same rights over the term of the project is also of critical importance for a private participant. The challenge is in drafting laws that are able to provide certainty and at the same time enough flexibility to accommodate any change that may be necessary to regulate the sector. Risks, Risk Allocation, and Risk Management Success of private participation in a project and the ability of a project to be financed on the basis of project finance (rather than asset or balance sheet finance) depends upon an appropriate distribution and management of risks associated with the project. Theoretically, risks should be allocated to the participant that is best able to either control or bear that risk. However, it is risk distribution that makes negotiation of infrastructure project documentation complicated, intense, and challenging.18 Consumer Issues The statutory as well as the contractual framework need to provide an adequate mechanism to handle consumer issues in order to provide a suitable framework for the implementation of the project. A credible, competent, fully functional, and independent sectoral regulatory agency would be the first critical step in this regard. 18 For a detailed discussion on risk identification, allocation, and management, see Joshi (2001), chapter 3. 76 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 4.3.1 Legal Framework in Electricity, Telecom, and National Highways1 In order to be effective, the law and policies ought to provide a clear framework for exercise of discretion by the executive authority in all aspects of project implementation such as selection of private participant, the manner of grant of rights, the rights th at would be granted, terms and conditions of the grant of rights, etc., as they impinge upon the risks associated with an economic ventu re. THE ELECTRICITY SECTOR At present, the Indian Electricity Act, 1910, the Electricity Supply Act, 1948, and the Electricity Regulatory Commissions Act, 1998 constitute the statutory framework for the sector. A comprehensive Bill, namely the Electricity Bill 2001, is expected to repeal all these three Acts and replace them by an overall legislation that would govern the entire electricity sector. The present framework governing the electricity sector allows three venues for private participation: generating companies; transmission licensees; and licensees for supply of electricity (or distribution licensees). A generating company is allowed to only establish generating stations and enter into an agreement with the state electricity board for the sale of electricity generated from such generating station. A generating company is allowed to sell electricity to a person other than the relevant state electricity board only with the prior approval of the competent government(s). A transmission licensee could be an inter-state transmission licensee or an intra-state transmission licensee. An inter-state transmission licensee has to be granted a transmission licence by the central government. It has to work under the direction, control, and supervision of the Central Transmission Utility. An intra-state transmission licensee has to be granted a transmission licence by the concerned state government. It has to work under the direction, control, and supervision of the relevant State Transmission Utility. A licensee to supply electricity (distribution licensee) can also notify that a generating station that is already established or would be established would form part of the licensee’s entire undertaking and should be considered as assets of the licensee under the licence so granted. The generating station that would form part of the licensee’s undertaking can even be outside the area for which the licence has been granted to it. The Indian Electricity Act, 1910 also contemplates a ‘bulk licensee’. A bulk licensee is a distribution licensee who is authorized to supply electricity to other licensees for distribution by them. Even though the legal framework allows for private participation in every aspect of the electricity sector, namely the generation, transmission, and distribution of electricity, private participation in the electricity sector has been concentrated mainly in the generation segment, and that too, by adopting the ‘generating company’ route. This is because the legal provisions governing private participation through other structures is not adequate to support large-scale private investment. The notable features in the Acts that increase the risks for licensees are as follows: Power of the State Electricity Board (SEB) to: • at any time and at its own discretion, permanently close down a generating station established by a licensee 2. • at any time, acquire/purchase any undertaking, generating station, or transmission line established by a licensee3. • to declare any generating station established by a licensee as a ‘controlled station’, thereby altering the framework governing its operation, tariff and acquisition4. • to regulate any expansion or replacement or works pertaining to a generating station established by a licensee 5. • to enter into the premises of and shut down any generating station established by a licensee for certain defaults under the ESA6. The state government has the power: • • • • • to to to to to revoke the licence granted to a licensee at any time after consulting the State Electricity Board 7. unilaterally vary the terms of the licence relating to the consequences of termination8. amend the licence so granted to a licensee at any time after consulting the State Electricity Board 9. direct the licensee to sell its undertaking in accordance with the directions of the state government10. give direction to a licensee in regard to the supply of energy to certain classes of customers11. 1 Each of these sectors is separately dealt with in detail 2 See Section 36 Electricity Supply Act (ESA), 1948. 3 See Section 37 ESA, 1948. 4 See Section 34 ESA, 1948. 5 See Section 44 ESA, 1948. 6 See Section 45 ESA, 1948. 7 See Section 4 (Indian Electricity Act) IEA, 1910. 8 See Section 10 IEA, 1910. 9 See Section 4A IEA, 1910. 10 See Section 5 IEA, 1910 and Section 6 IEA, 1910. 11 See Section 22A IEA, 1910. in Joshi (2001). The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 77 In comparison to the licensee route, the generating company route has lesser risks associated with it under the legal framework, as all these provisions relating to the licensee are not applicable to a generating company. THE NATIONAL HIGHWAYS SECTOR The National Highways Act, 1956 was amended in 1995 to specifically vest the central government with the discretion to ‘enter into an agreement with any person in relation to the development and maintenance of the whole or any part of a national highway’.12 Thus, private participation in the development and maintenance of national highways has now become possible through a contractual arrangement between the central government and the private entity(ies). Certain basic elements for private participation are still missing in the legal framework. The National Highways Act specifies that national highways shall vest in the Union of India.13 This provision inherently limits the scope and nature of rights that can be vested in a private developer as the relevant provisions only state that the government can enter into an agreement with the private participant in relation to the ‘development and maintenance’ of a national highway. This limits the scope of private participation to ‘development’ and ‘maintenance’; and not to activities such as ‘operation’ and ‘management’ of the national highway, development of land appurtenant to national highways, etc. Another concern for any private entity is the scope and powers of the National Highways Authority of India (NHAI) constituted under the NHAI Act, 1988. The jurisdiction of the NHAI spans over a national highway or part of a national highway which has been ‘vested’ in it or ‘entrusted’ to it by the central government. Both terms have significantly different legal consequences: through ‘vesting’, there can be an absolute transfer of interest in the property, depending on the nature of the vesting; whereas ‘entrustment’ would mean transfer in trust for a specific purpose only. This is significant in view of the fact that it is the NHAI, and not the central government itself, that has been constituted as the authority who would be signing the Concession Agreements for private participation in the national highway sector. Unless there is clarity as to the scope of powers and jurisdiction of the NHAI itself, the very basis of the Concession Agreement through which rights are sought to be granted to private developers, would be in question14. Aspects that could be of worry to large-scale and long-term private participation would include: • Mandatory vesting of all national highways with the Union which precludes vesting of any proprietary interests in private parties over the national highway itself. • Authority of the NHAI to enter into the concession agreements is questionable as it is the Union government which is mandated under the NH Act to enter into the agreement with the private developer. The NHAI Act does not vest adequate corresponding powers or authority with the NHAI for vesting the rights and powers with a private entity as are provided for in the concession agreement. • Framework for the determination and levy of fee for the use of the national highways does not adequately cover and address critical issues such as: certainty of criteria for determining the fee; protection of the right of the private participants and lenders to participate in the process of determination of fee; certainty as to the notification of the fee by the government; and certainty of the actual capital cost of the facility to be taken into consideration. • Inadequacy of powers conferred on the private participant to enforce the collection, retention, and appropriation of the fee from the users. 12 13 14 See Section 8A National Highways Act. See Section 4 National Highways Act. For a greater discussion on the scope and limits of private participation under the NH Act, the NHAI Act, and the Model Concession Agreement, see Joshi (2001), pp. 508–40. Next would be an adequate mechanism to establish the various basic principles for determination of tariff that would be protected and enforced by law. Another step would be to establish the basic principles that would determine and test the validity and legitimacy of consumer issues. The Supreme Court of India has identified certain principles for determining the validity of writ petitions being filed in relation to a public interest litigation (PIL).19 19 The principles established by the Supreme Court in this regard include: • Only a person acting bona fide and having sufficient—interest in the proceeding of public interest litigation will have the ability to file a valid PIL. A person prompted by personal gain or private A CRITIQUE OF THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK PRIVATE PARTICIPATION FOR Even though Indian laws do not clearly prohibit private participation, and may in fact specifically state and provide for private participation, most of them still have certain profit or political motive or any oblique consideration cannot file a valid PIL. The actions should be for specific redressal of issue relating to public injury or violation of statutory or legal or constitutional principles. • The relief would be corrective and not compensatory in nature. • The remedy would generally be negotiated or quasi negotiated rather than imposed. PIL involves collaboration and co-operation. 78 India Infrastructure Report 2002 critical drawbacks which effectively deter private participation in the relevant infrastructure sector. Some of these drawbacks are as follows: • Law may not allow for private interest to be created in an infrastructure facility: This drawback can be found in the municipal laws of many states which mandatorily vest many critical urban infrastructure facilities in the local municipal authority. For example in relation to water supply, municipal legislations of many states mandate that all water treatment plants and distribution facilities within the given municipal area shall vest in the local municipal authority. The immediate effect of such a provision is that any such facility, as and when developed, becomes the property of, and falls under the complete control of, the local authority. • Law may mandate certain services to be provided only through a specific statutory body/authority: A number of states have enacted laws to establish specific authorities that are vested with the exclusive authority to establish infrastructure facilities and provide specific services within a specified area. For example, water supply and sewerage boards are generally vested with the exclusive authority to supply water and undertake sewerage treatment in the area under their jurisdiction. • Law may not provide for adequate protection of private investment: The legal framework may provide wide and easily exercisable discretionary powers to the government/ government authority to take over a facility established by a private entity. For example, under the Indian Electricity Act, 1910 read with the Electricity Supply Act, 1948, the facilities established by a licensee under the IEA, 1910 can be taken over by the SEB through a relatively easy procedure of adequate notification. When private participation was allowed through the generating company route, these laws had to be amended to specifically protect the assets developed by generating companies from such wide discretionary powers. In the absence of such specific amendments, would not have been possible to obtain private investment in the generation sector. • Law may not adequately provide for vesting of all relevant rights required for the development and implementation of an infrastructure project with a private entity. • Law may not provide for creation of security interest over the infrastructure facility in favour of lenders. Lenders • The legal proceeding should be for enforcement of rights of persons who are otherwise unable to enforce their rights. • When the petitioner seeks any relief to serve his self interest, apart from that of the community, that relief would be refused. • PIL should not be allowed to be misused for vindicating enmity or rivalry. • PIL is not for settling disputes between two individual parties. are, technically, third parties to any agreement/arrangement between the government and the private developers. However, they typically have large financial stakes in infrastructure projects. The laws governing various infrastructure sectors in India do not address the aspect of rights of lenders to a project. Even in an infrastructure sector such as telecommunications, which has a high level of private participation, the law and the licence provide for the direct taking over of the facility by the government in the event of a default by the licensee or the termination of the licence. The law as well as the licence itself does not provide a secure basis for the establishment, recognition, and enforcement of the rights of the lenders to a project. It is essential to address this aspect in order to ensure that lenders’ interests in a project are adequately safeguarded. • Law may not provide for due recognition and enforcement of lenders’ rights: In order to enable successful project financing of infrastructure projects it is critical that the relevant law enables the creation of the security interest in favour of the lenders in the assets of the project, recognizes all the necessary rights relating to the continued implementation of the project, and allows for a secure and speedy enforcement of such security rights. This is a function of not only the infrastructure specific laws but also the laws relating to banking, property, enforcement of rights relating to property, and civil procedure followed by courts. It is not really possible to conclude a pure project finance transaction in India. All financing of infrastructure projects in India has a large component of recourse against the equity sponsors or have a large component of guarantee based financing. This situation is a direct result of the existing legal framework relating not only to the specific structures but other general law relating to enforcement of security rights. This was one of the main issues that held up the adequate financing of the basic telephone service projects and certain cellular projects in 1995–7. This led to a move to formulate a direct agreement between the government of India and the lenders, acting through a security agent, that would allow for rights to be created in favour of the lenders in the licence and the project and also to regulate the rights of the government to terminate a licence and take over the network. However, even though an amendment was circulated to the licensees indicating that: (a) rights in relation to the licence and the project can be created in favour of the lenders in accordance with the direct agreement; and also that (b) the rights of the government to terminate the project will be subject to the rights of the lenders under the direct agreement, till date the draft of the direct agreement has not been finalized or approved by the government. • Law may not provide for imposition of tariff/fee/toll for use of the infrastructure facility/service so provided: It is common to find that the legal framework of a specific The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 79 infrastructure sector may not allow for, or be completely silent on, the imposition of tariff in relation to the concerned infrastructure facilities. Many state laws relating to urban infrastructure such as roads, bridges, and water supply do not support imposition of tariffs in relation to the use of such facilities. • Law may not provide for or support imposition of regulated yet commercially viable tariffs/fee/tolls: Often it is found that even if the legal framework provides for imposition of tariff for use of a specific infrastructure facility, the tariff so mandated is not one that could provide a commercially viable proposition to support large-scale investment of private capital, for instance in the case of roads and bridges. Many states do have a Tolls Act that enables the levy and collection by the government of a tariff on the use of a state road or bridge. However, the level of the tariff and the extent to which it can be revised is extremely low and commercially unviable. Similarly, the framework for the levy, determination, collection, and revision of the general rates of tariff for supply and usage of potable water in urban areas do not provide for commercial viability of investment. • Law may not allow or support a mechanism for a procedure that allows for participation of the private developers in the determination of tariff: To take an example, the Electricity Regulatory Commissions Act, 1998 empowers the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission and the State Electricity Regulatory Commissions to determine tariff for the sale of electricity within their respective jurisdiction. The provisions that provide the guidelines for the exercise of such power by the respective commissions however do not mandate participation of the private developers in the relevant aspect of the electricity sector for which the tariff may be determined by the respective commissions.20 • Law may not have adequate provision for collection and appropriation of tariff/fee/toll by the private entity from the users of the infrastructure facility: This is a drawback that can be commonly spotted in state laws relating to levy and collection of tolls on roads and bridges as well as municipal laws governing urban infrastructure such as the water sector. In the absence of a specific right to retain and appropriate tariff, there is always the possibility of challenging the revenue stream from the facility as being a public revenue 20 See Section 28 and Section 29 Electricity Regulatory Commissions Act (ERCA), 1998. Section 28 of the ERCA, 1998 governs the determination of tariff by the Central Commission while Section 29 governs the determination of tariff by the State Commission. The two provisions stipulate certain principles which the commissions would be ‘guided by’ in the determination of tariff. The principles so stated are therefore not mandatory factors but only guidelines. The principles so stipulated as guidelines themselves do not provide for the participation of the private developers in the process of determination of tariff by the commissions. stream that should go into the consolidated fund of the state rather than a private revenue stream that is the property of the private developer. This is particularly so in cases such as tolls on roads and bridges where most of the state laws governing tolls on roads and bridges specifically mandate that the amounts so collected shall be part of the consolidated fund of the state. • Law may not provide for an adequate independent regulatory mechanism: The mere establishment of a regulator is not sufficient. The law has to provide and protect the independence of the regulator from not only political/ government influence but private influence as well. A general regulator will typically therefore not be as effective as a sector specific regulator, given the detailed technical considerations that are involved in tariff setting. • Law may not provide for adequate dispute settlement mechanism: Delay in the implementation of the project caused due to (expected) delay in the settlement of disputes will ultimately get factored into the cost of the infrastructure facility, and could even result in making the project itself unviable. Disputes in relation to an infrastructure project can arise at every stage, right from the very beginning. Since it may not be a viable proposition to always establish a separate mechanism intended solely for settlement of disputes relating to infrastructure projects, settlement of disputes through conciliation and arbitration is often regarded as a faster and better mechanism in this regard. Speedy enforcement of arbitration agreements in the law would therefore help considerably. The presence of an independent regulator who can pre-empt, and effectively redress situations of dispute, is also a critical necessity. • Law may impose excessive taxes/duties in relation to the process of implementation of infrastructure development: It is common to find that the Union laws impose a specific set of taxes, and the laws of the relevant state impose another set of taxes, and to compound these, municipal authorities also impose taxes on various aspects of an infrastructure project. If the tax laws are not reviewed and harmonized, it is possible for the private participants and the project itself to be subject to multiple taxation that could shrink its demand considerably. CONTRACTUAL FRAMEWORK The contractual framework established by the participants for each specific project has to be within the overall framework provided by statutory regulations. It is the contractual framework that actually governs the day to day implementation of the project. The contractual framework reflects the risk sharing arrangements agreed to between the parties. 80 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Even with an excellent statutory framework, if the contractual framework for a particular project is not adequate, the project could fail to obtain adequate debt and equity funding. The contractual framework also fills the space and the lacunae left by the overall statutory framework. A complex web of interdependent contractual obligations often arise in the implementation of infrastructure projects. It is a common and perhaps inappropriate criticism of private participation in infrastructure projects that complicated contracts are used by parties to ‘mystify and cloud the issues’. It is important to understand that each of the contracts in this ‘web’ has a specific and critical purpose to serve, the absence of which would result in vagueness and ambiguity of obligations and rights of various participants in the project. This aspect is sought to be illustrated through the example of the Power Purchase Agreement and related documents. A ‘core’ document (for example, a Power Purchaser Agreement, or a licence or a concession agreement) usually forms the basis on which the entire contractual framework emerges. The ‘core document’ is one between the developer and the relevant government or authority which establishes the rights of the private participants to develop and implement the project. From the core document there emerges a system of contractual documents which tie down all the participants in the project to each other and establish the framework that enables the equity and debt financing of the project and its implementation. A typical contractual framework comprises of the construction contracts, the operation and maintenance contracts, the equity financing arrangements, the debt financing arrangements, and security documents. The basic aim of the contractual framework is to ensure that all the major participants to the project have obligations towards completing their portion of the project implementation and to ensure their direct privity/ relationship to the lenders, in order to ensure adequate security for the debt financing of the project on a partial recourse or non recourse basis.21 A diagrammatic representation of the main contractual documents forming a typical contractual framework for a power project in India can be seen in Fig. 4.3.1. 21 Due to the quantum of financing required for the implementation of an infrastructure project, it is not a viable option to undertake debt financing on the usual recourse basis as in the case of industrial projects. Debt finance for infrastructure projects is sought to be raised on the basis of the project itself with the main security being the revenue stream generated from the operation of the project. The emphasis of the security structure is therefore not on the assets of the borrower itself but in the due implementation and operation of the project. There is usually no or limited recourse to the private entities actually implementing the project. This structure for debt financing is referred to as ‘project financing’ or ‘non recourse financing’. For further discussion on debt financing of infrastructure projects see Joshi (2001), chapters 2, 3, and 5. From these interlocking set of contracts22, it is, therefore, clear that the contractual framework governing the implementation of a project is as critical to the implementation to the project as the statutory framework. The statutory framework determines the sanctity of the contractual framework and determines the ability of the parties to enforce their rights under the contractual framework. UNIFORM LAW FOR INFRASTRUCTURE PROJECTS As discussed earlier in this paper, the Constitutional framework in India does not permit for a single law governing grant of rights for development of projects in all the infrastructure sectors. The Constitution of India, through Article 246 read with the Seventh Schedule, distributes various legislative fields between the Union Parliament and the state legislature. The Seventh Schedule provides for three lists of legislative fields: the Union List, the State List, and the Concurrent List. Table 4.3.1 depicts an indicative list of items in the three list. Further, the Constitution of India, and the state laws, vest municipalities and panchayats23 with responsibilities and jurisdiction over certain infrastructure facilities within their territorial jurisdiction. Matters listed under the Constitution as capable of being delegated to municipal bodies pertain largely to urban planing, including town planning; regulation of land use; water supply within the municipal jurisdiction; and public amenities. A majority of matters that may be delegated to panchayats pertain to agricultural and rural development. Panchayats in Scheduled Areas24 have greater powers under the Panchayat (Extension to Scheduled Areas) Act, 1996, as may be specifically vested with them by each state. The authority of the gram sabha that could be relevant for infrastructure projects under this Act are: (i) the right to be consulted before any decision is made with respect to acquisition of land in the Scheduled Areas for development projects and before resettling and rehabilitating persons affected by such projects in the Scheduled Areas; (ii) the recommendations of the gram sabha are mandatory prior to the grant of prospecting licence or a mining lease for minor minerals in the Scheduled Areas; (iii) the power to prevent alienation of land in the Scheduled Areas and to take appropriate action to restore any unlawfully alienated land of a Scheduled Tribe; and (iv) the power to control local plans and resources for such plans. 22 For a more detailed discussion on each of these agreements, see Joshi (2001), pp. 356–71. 23 Panchayats are local self-government bodies at the village level. 24 Areas so declared under the Fifth or Sixth Schedules to the Constitution of India. The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 81 Share Pledge Agreement Security Agent Agreement $ Loan Agreements JVA/SHA Rs Loan Agreements Security Agreements Inter Creditor Agreement Direct Agreements PPA Payment Security Guarantees TRA Hypothecation Equity Funding Agreements Sponsor Support Agreement Common Agreement Mortgage Equity Agreements and Debt Financing Agreements Fuel Supply Agreement Fuel Transport Agreement PPA EPC Agreement EPC Sub Contract Agreements O&M Agreement O&M Sub Contract Agreements Figure 4.3.1 Illustrative Contractual Framework: Power Project. Notes: PPA JVA EPC O&M TRM SHA power purchase agreement joint venture agreement engineering, procurement, construction operations & maintenance trust retention account agreement shareholder agreement 82 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Table 4.3.1 Distribution of Activities in Accordance with the Seventh Schedule and Article 246 of the Constitution Union List (List 1) Railways Highways Shipping and Navigation Major Ports Airways, Aircraft, Air Navigation, Aerodromes Posts and Telegraphs Regulation and Development of Oil fields and Mineral Oil Resources Regulation and Development of Interstate Rivers and River Valleys Foreign Loans, Banking Tax on Income (other than agricultural income) Currency, Foreign Exchange State List (List II) Roads, Bridges, Ferries, and such communication as is not specified in List 1 Water supplies, Irrigation, Canals, drainage—subject to power of Union Land, Land tenure Regulation of Mines and Mineral Development, subject to power of Union Gas and Gas works Local Government Taxes on Consumption or sale of Electricity Rates of Stamp Duty Any law governing the grant of rights/licence/concession for development of infrastructure projects would therefore have to take into account these aspects. The alternative to sector specific laws is for the legislative bodies to enact a general law in relation to the sectors that fall within their jurisdiction. The Union Parliament could enact a law allowing for private participation in the infrastructure sectors specified in the Union List and the Concurrent List. Each state could conceivably enact a relevant law in relation to the infrastructure sectors falling within its jurisdiction. A number of states in India are in the process of drafting laws for facilitating infrastructure projects within their territories. The state of Gujarat has already enacted such a law, which we briefly discuss below. GUJARAT BOT LAW25 The Gujarat Infrastructure Development Act, 1999, (the ‘GIDA’ or ‘Act’) was the first law of its kind in India. Enacted by the state of Gujarat, it focuses on facilitating infrastructure development through private participation within its territory. The Act establishes the Gujarat Infrastructure Development Board (GIDB), comprising of members appointed by the state government, and provides for the basic framework along which the GIDB would function and facilitate private participation in infrastructure projects. Several options for such participation are envisaged in a schedule to the law (build, operate, transfer (BOT); build, operate, lease, and transfer (BOLT); renovate, operate, and transfer (ROT)). The scheme for the concession agreement is to be separately prescribed. The nature of projects listed as falling 25 For a discussion on the same, especially its creation see Chakraborty, Atanu (2000). Concurrent List (List III) Ports other than Major Ports Shipping and Navigation in Inland Waterways Electricity Transfer of Property other than Agricultural Land Acquisition and Requisition of property Contracts Economic and Social Planning Price Control Commercial and Industrial Monopolies within the jurisdiction of the Act are specified in Schedule 1 to the Act consistent with state subjects under the Constitution. Schedule 1 also mentions ‘Power Generation, Transmission and Distribution Systems’, which is in the Concurrent List. While facilitating projects on this subject, due compliance would have to be made with the Union laws prevalent in this sector. The Act provides for selection of the project proponent through the process of competitive bidding. Direct negotiations are also envisaged in the event that proposals are submitted not as response to any specific bidding process, but by the initiative of the concerned entity(ies). The law prescribes selection of bidders in an open bidding process based on three successive sets of criteria: prequalification; technical; and financial. Of these, the Act lays down the criteria for financial evaluation. The Act allows the project developer to charge fees as specified in the concession agreement. Such fees can also be revised, based on criteria specified in the agreement. The Act recognizes that rate of inflation and variation in rate of foreign exchange are factors which may be taken into account for revision of fees. As financial security, the project developer is required to open an escrow account or execute a performance bond. The Act identifies several ways in which the state government or its agency can provide assistance for the project, such as through participation in the equity of the project company; extending of subsidies; senior or subordinate loans; executing government guarantees; operation of escrow account; conferment of development rights in respect of any land; and incentives in the form of exemption or deferral of taxes. The Act also considers the possible scenarios which may emerge from termination of the concession agreement with a project promoter, and provides for: The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 83 • payment of compensation to the developer in accordance with the concession agreement; • take over of the project without repaying the investments made by the developer upon termination for default of the developer, but at the same time assuming liabilities of the developer for repayment of loans taken in lieu of the project; • new concession agreement with a person recommended by the lenders, on the same terms as specified in the earlier concession agreement. The GIDA is in the nature of an overarching framework. Almost all of its specific provisions would require greater elaboration of basic principles and criteria in order to make it a strong statute. For instance, the basic principles of the concession agreement, the aspects that would require elaboration in the bidding process, the factors to be considered ‘relevant’ for selection of the project promoter, and monitoring of the project during its lifetime are some of the aspects that the law could make clearer. This would mean guided exercise of executive decision by the government/statutory authorities, and the establishment of essential criteria that cannot be deviated from. One example where this has been achieved is in the Philippines statute governing infrastructure projects26. 4.4 OPENING DOORS TO ‘THE OUTSIDER’: THE RIGHT TO INFORMATION27 Abha Singhal Joshi In the government’s role as a provider of social and economic services—policing, roads, schools, bridges, ration shops— the right to information of its citizens has never been enforced and has rarely been invoked. People at all levels have continued to suffer the colonial regime of secrecy which has been enforced through enactments like the Official Secrets Act of 1923—a law which dominates the mindset of the public official from the clerk to the highest levels of government. The operation of this legislation has been supported by other restrictive provisions contained in the Indian Evidence Act, the Code of Conduct for Civil Servants, and other practices such as marking the most ordinary documents as ‘secret’ or ‘confidential’. Information has been treated as the exclusive domain of government and requests for the most banal bits of information are treated with apathy or animosity. In this regime, the functioning of information ‘touts’ has flourished in every activity and a parallel system of acquiring information, whether from ‘closed door’ cabinet meetings or from one’s own service or electricity records, has developed. Despite court rulings to the effect that the right to information is basic, there has been little use of the same right for betterment and accountability. This has been so because of (i) the blanket restrictions that arise out the Official Secrets Act 1923, wherein under an undefined ‘public interest’, virtually all information can be denied; (ii) poor state of records, and even poorer information retrieval mechanisms; and (iii) untimeliness and poor form of the little information provided. Decentralization, the advancement of democracy, political development, and the emergence of NGOs, and multilateral agencies (MLA’s) insistence on transparency have all led to a realization that a right to information would have to come about. The response of the state in India to the issues raised by the call for openness has been to legislate in the form of Freedom of Information (FOI) or Access to Information Acts. While countries like Sweden and the USA have FOI Acts in place since the 1960s, other countries that have recently legislated the right to information are the UK (2000), South Africa (2000), Ireland, and, closer home, Japan, the Philippines, and Thailand. The right to know has been held to be inherent in Article 19 (1) (a) of the Constitution of India, which guarantees the right to freedom of speech and expression. The basic argument, even if it pertains to the right of the media to publish and disseminate information, is that a person must have information in order to formulate and express his or her views. This right includes the right to express criticism or dissent of any policy or decision. The right to know, then, is closely related to another fundamental right under Article 21 of the Constitution––the right to life and personal liberty. The right to information is a must for realizing the right to equality guaranteed by Article 14 of the Constitution. It stands to reason that in a decision making situation of large social import, all parties concerned must have equal access to facts, and a free flow of information would ensure transparency and in turn, absence of arbitrariness. 26 The Philippines’ statute R.A. No. 6957, entitled ‘An Act for Authorizing the Financing, Construction, Operation and Maintenance of Infrastructure Projects by the Private Sector and for Other Purposes’, provides a valuable illustration of the nature of aspects that such a law on this subject could cover. 27 In India Infrastructure Report 2001, Section 5.8, I had very briefly commented on the Information and the Draft Bill. This section takes the discussion further. 84 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 4.4.1 The Freedom Of Information Bill The Freedom of Information Bill was first drafted by the Shourie Committee,1 whose terms of reference were: a. To examine the need and feasibility of either a full fledged Right to Information Act, or its introduction in a phased manner to meet the needs of open and responsive government. b. To identify specific areas where right to information can be built into the working procedures and system, especially in large departmental undertakings, including railways, telecommunications, postal services, passports and banking at the central level. c. To examine the internal working procedures (of departments and governments) with a view to introducing greater openness and transparency in handling of employee grievances and internal consultation. d. To examine the rules framework with particular reference to the existing conduct rules and manual of office procedures with a view to introducing greater openness and transparency in government working, including dealings with employees. e. To examine the nature and content of training to promote greater openness and more customer responsive public dealings. The Working Group consisted of ten persons amongst whom were consumer rights activist H.D. Shourie as the Chairperson, Soli Sorabjee, a senior advocate and the present the Attorney General of India, and eight civil servants representing various central government departments. The Working Group gave its report in a period of approximately four months, during which period it held a total of six meetings to arrive at the draft. The Group consisted mainly of government servants, which surely would have narrowed the perspective and concerns of the deliberations. Since the Group was dealing with issues where sections of the public would be pitted against the government, a larger representation from the public in the Working Group would have been necessary. The composition of the Group, was very urban-centric as well as central government oriented. Availability of information is of particular importance to governance at the local level––at the level of panchayats and municipalities, besides at the level of the state government. However, not all concerns of the public were reflected. The Report did not suggest any concrete steps to simplify the existing procedures. The Report and the Draft Bill also did not indicate how the central law is to function qua pre-existing systems of information, such as under the Panchayati Raj Acts in various states, or the right to have information under the various land and revenue laws of the states. The Group consulted only two people in the course of formulating its recommendations––namely, P.B. Sawant the Chairman of the Press Council of India and A.K. Venkat Subramaniam, Secretary, Department of Consumer Affairs. Their responses are not mentioned in the Report. The Report is otherwise silent on the process of consultation, if any, with various interest groups. The Report makes no mention of the materials referred to except some laws of other countries but omits to mention the relevance or content of these laws.2 The result was a somewhat skimpy and insipid report which sidestepped most of the terms of reference and presented a draft Right to Information Bill which left much to be desired. At the departmental and cabinet committee levels, not much homework went into the Bill, except for the dropping of certain good provisions, such as the provision for a Council for Right to Information and an independent appellate body. The lack of application is further reflected in the Hindi version of the Bill, which is a poor and cryptic translation of the English version, with unfriendly and even wrong usage. The Bill, after being introduced in the Lok Sabha in July 2000, was debated on for 40 odd minutes and Home Affairs referred to the Parliamentary Standing Committee on Home Affairs. The Committee heard witnesses which included senior activists and NGOs working on the issue.3 The Committee submitted its report to Parliament4 on 25 July 2001. The report enumerates the suggestions and recommendations of the witnesses but does not make any major or concrete recommendations for changes in the Bill. The Bill is now back on the table of the House and will, in all probability, be passed in its present form. 1 2 Working Group on Right to Information and Promotion of Open and Transparent Government, Government of India, 1977. For a detailed critique, see Abha Singhal Joshi, ‘An Appraisal of the Report of the Working Group on Right to Information and Open and Transparent Government’, Commonwealth Human Rights Initiative, 1998. 3 The witnesses include Madhav Godbole, Manubhai Shah, A.G. Noorani, P.B. Sawant, Commonwealth Human Rights Initiative, and Mazdoor Kisaan Shakti Sangathan. 4 Department Related Parliamentary Standing Committee on Home Affairs, Seventy Eighth Report on Freedom of Information Bill, 2000. RIGHT TO INFORMATION LAWS ELSEWHERE The processes followed in drafting the ‘Freedom of Information Bill’ in India is in sharp contrast with the processes followed in other countries which have drafted right to information laws in recent times. South Africa, which passed its law on right to information last year,28 drafted its Bill after thorough research and consultation with various departments, institutions, and ministries and government departments/offices (including the premiers of provinces, the Public Protector, Attorney General, South African Police Services, South African 28 Promotion of Access to Information Act, 2000. The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 85 Defence Force and the National Intelligence Agency, the Chief Justice and Judges President of the Supreme Court). Similarly, the Open Democracy Advisory Forum (consisting of more than 60 organizations mainly representing civil society) and various parastatals and non-governmental bodies participated extensively in the deliberations. As a result, their law, though somewhat detailed, takes into account various factors like a not completely literate population. The processes gone through were also useful in educating the public about the law. In the United Kingdom, known to have one of the most closed systems of governance, the government brought out a White Paper on freedom of information, on which comments from the public were sought. The government had also placed the detailed White Paper on a website for further reach. Although the Bill, when drafted, diluted many of the recommendations of the White Paper, wide publicity enabled civil society groups to engage with their Members of Parliament (MPs) and negotiate better provisions of the law. Flaws in the Laws Freedom of information laws have been passed by several Indian states29 in the last four years and the central government’s Freedom of Information Bill 2000 is pending in Parliament. The biggest drawback is the array of exceptions in all the laws, all so worded as to enable the continuance of withholding of information on vague and specious grounds. Tamil Nadu (1997) and Maharashtra (2000) take the lead with 22 exceptions each, with several sub-sections to them, where the bulk of the provisions relate to information that cannot be given. The exceptions are widely worded and contain an unspecified and vague ‘likelihood’ of harm to various aspects of government’s functioning. For example, the Tamil Nadu and Maharashtra enactments both contain clause 3 (2) (q) which restricts the release of information ‘the disclosure of which could lead to improper gain or advantage or would prejudice: i. the competitive position of a department or other public body or authority ii. negotiations or the effective conduct of personnel management or commercial or contractual activities.’ These two Acts also have the onerous provision of entitling only a person who ‘bonafide’ requires information, to ask 29 Tamil Nadu, Goa (1997), Rajasthan, Maharashtra (2000), Delhi (2001). Madhya Pradesh passed an Act in 1998, which did not come into force for want of presidential assent. Madhya Pradesh, however, has a series of executive orders whereby government departments are required to give information to the people. Uttar Pradesh has a Code for Access to Information, which has been made applicable through an executive instruction. for it. This single provision strikes at the very root of the right, as it seeks to maintain the status of treating an ordinary person asking for information with distrust and suspicion. Other provisions in other state laws as well as the central law are equally open to misuse by their very nature. ‘Prejudice’ to the sovereignty and integrity of India, conduct of centre– state relations, and public safety and order are grounds for refusal to be found in all the enactments. Under some Acts, information which would ‘harm the frankness and candour’ of internal discussions can be refused! Many Exemptions In the central FOI Bill, ‘cabinet papers including records of the deliberations of the Council of Ministers, Secretaries and other officers’ are all exempted from being disclosed. Practically the entire decision making process on policy is sought to be kept secret. Yet no timeline is prescribed for when the same is eligible for disclosure. Moreover, there are certain institutional exemptions given in Part A of the Schedule, under which the Intelligence Bureau, Research and Analysis Wing of the Cabinet Secretariat, Directorate of Revenue Intelligence, Central Economic Intelligence Bureau, Directorate of Enforcement, and the Narcotics Control Bureau are exempt from the operation of the law. The government has also kept to itself the power to include more organizations in the Schedule. These kinds of blanket exemptions are untenable and the extension of the protection even to the administrative activities of these organizations is not wise. For example, tenders called for by any of these organizations should have been in the public domain as with other departments. Section 9 of the FOI Bill adds further grounds for refusal, some of which, such as requests which are too general in nature or requests for unusually voluminous information, are valid. The problem clause is 9(c) which allows requests to be refused if it ‘relates to information that is contained in published material available to the public’. This clause, in the absence of casting a corresponding duty on public bodies to publish and make available certain kinds of information at an affordable price, would give rise to several problems of accessibility, such as the inability of people to access information contained in highly priced publications. None of the above exceptions are subject to overriding public interest, that is, that disclosure may be allowed if it is in the benefit of the public to have the information, as opposed to the harm that non-disclosure would cause. This is an essential aspect of modern right to information laws, and has been included in the laws of South Africa, United Kingdom, and Japan. Under the Japanese law, certain kinds of private or corporate information is exempted from disclosure, but these can also be disclosed where disclosure is necessary to protect a person’s life, health, livelihood, or 86 India Infrastructure Report 2002 property, or where, on balance the benefits to disclosure outweigh the interests protected by non-disclosure. Section 11 of the Indian FOI Bill which pertains to notifying a third party about whom information is sought to be disclosed, allows disclosure in case the ‘public interest in disclosure outweighs in importance any possible harm or injury to the interest of such third party’. However, curiously, it specifically leaves ‘trade and commercial secrets protected by law’ out of the ambit of the public interest disclosure clause. This could be a cause for serious concern and would give rise to a situation where trade and commercial secrets, once given into the confidence of the government, would always remain inaccessible, public interest notwithstanding. By the application of this section, a company like the Union Carbide Corporation could claim secrecy for their patented antidotes to Methylisocyanate, even though revealing it could mean curing hundreds suffering from the after-effects of a deadly gas that leaked due to the gross negligence of the third party in the first place! That the nature of the widely worded exceptions are sure to be misused is already becoming evident from the responses which information seekers are getting in various forums. In Rajasthan, where the right to information Act came into force in May 2000, an application for records of Panchayat expenditure was made by the MKSS30 under the Panchayat Act rules. Photocopies of development records pertaining to various schemes such as Indira Awaas, etc. were refused, citing a Gram Sabha resolution to the effect that giving the records would create a breach of peace and a law and order problem and would also create a hurdle in performance of official functions of the panchayat! OBLIGATION STATES TO PUBLISH IN ACTS OF CERTAIN A positive aspect of the FOI Bill as well as the Karnataka and Delhi Acts is the obligation31 cast on public bodies to maintain, catalogue, and publish their records, publish their own powers, duties, norms of functioning, rules, regulations, instructions, manuals, etc. They are also under an obligation to publish all relevant facts concerning important decisions and policies that affect the public while announcing such decisions and policies and to give reasons for their decisions, whether administrative or quasi-judicial to those affected by the decisions. Moreover, they are required, before initiating any project, to ‘publish or communicate to the public generally or to the persons affected or likely to be affected 30 Mazdoor Kisaan Shakti Sangathan, a movement in the backward areas of Rajasthan. 31 Section 4, FOI Bill, 2000, Section 4, Delhi Right to Information Act, 2001 and Section 3, Karnataka Right to Information Act, 2000. Rajasthan has a diluted version of this provision in Section 12-A. by the project in particular, the facts available to it or to which it has reasonable access which in its opinion should be known to them in the best interests of maintenance of democratic principles’. The positive and proactive nature of this provision is limited by two requirements. The first relates to limiting the giving of information to ‘before initiating any project’. Although this would give the stakeholders an opportunity to put in their dissent or concerns on the project, there is a likelihood of their getting out of the process altogether once the project has begun. The public body would not be under a duty to inform the public of subsequent changes before incorporating them. Section 4 (c), in turn, only requires relevant facts concerning important decisions and policies that affect the public to be published while announcing such decisions. This provision leaves out entirely the duty to proactively inform people of other things which are not ‘projects’. For instance, information concerning the health and security of people, information relating to climatic or weather conditions, natural disasters like floods and cyclones, or pollution and the environment are thereby left out. Much of this kind of information is not only in the domain and control of government but it is government alone that has the resources to spread the information cheaply and quickly through its various networks at all levels. In particular, information related to disposal of nuclear wastes ought to be made available. Secondly, the duty to inform is restricted to facts ‘to which it has reasonable access’ and ‘which in its opinion’ should be known to them. Both are manifestations of the wide discretion that runs through the whole legislation. PROCEDURES IGNORED FOR OBTAINING INFORMATION The laws are equally weak in thinking through the procedure for getting information. Although most Acts, including the FOI Bill have provision for oral requests, none of the laws have a provision for acknowledging the request. The apprehension that in the absence of a requirement to give a receipt for the request, one would never see one’s application again, or hear from the department, is very real, considering the fate of even First Information Reports (FIRs) made at the police stations. The requirement for charging fees is likewise left vague and may be a cause for deterring potential seekers of information if the fee is kept too high, as is the case in Goa, where every request is to be accompanied by a fee of a hundred rupees, an amount not easy to procure for an individual. This kind of fee structure, by its very nature, excludes a large section of the population from trying to access information. There is no provision for The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 87 waiver of fee for the poor or if the information is sought in the public interest. Some laws, like the Rajasthan Act, specifically mention that information will not be given if the fee is not paid. Others, like the Delhi Act, prescribe a minimum charge equivalent to ‘the cost of processing and making available the information’. Only Internal Appeals Against Denial The procedure for accessing information in the FOI Bill becomes even more cumbersome when it comes to appealing decisions which refuse information. The Act gives only two ‘internal’ appeals, that is, appeals to government from its own decision. The lack of an independent appeal mechanism, which is internationally considered a sine qua non for a disclosure law, strikes at the very heart of the enactment. Moreover, one would be unable to move the civil courts as laid down by Section 15. Ultimately, an aggrieved person would have to move the High Court by way of writ jurisdiction, which takes us back to the position prior to the passing of the enactment. Read together with the lack of penalties for wrongful disclosure, the law is completely lacking in accountability provisions (which was the problem to be addressed in the first place) and seems to put a premium on refusals and delays. The state laws, except for those in Tamil Nadu and Maharashtra, are somewhat better in this regard. Goa prescribes the Administrative Tribunal as an appellate authority, while Rajasthan has the District Vigilance Committees at the district level and the Civil Services Appellate Tribunal as the authority. Delhi makes a provision for appeals to the Public Grievances Commission. Most of the states also set up a Council for Right to Information as a monitoring and implementing body. This useful provision is left out of the FOI Bill, although it was there in the Bill as proposed by the Shourie Committee. A body like this is essential in a scenario where the main hurdle in information disclosure is mindset and attitudes. An overseeing body could regulate and facilitate the training and orientation of public personnel as well as monitor developments and make suggestions on the operation of the law. ‘Whistleblowing’ Needs to be Protected The new legislative regime for right to information must take into account the protection of whistleblowers. ‘Whistleblowing’ is the exposure by an employee, who is privy to certain information, of wrongdoing which can harm the public interest. By its very nature, whistleblowing is a risky thing for the person who reveals information. In the context of India, as elsewhere, whistleblowing has often been attended with serious consequences like transfers, even suspension, or worse still, being kept on a job without actual work being allocated. Whistleblowing, therefore, must be protected in order to secure and protect from attack those employees who follow their conscience, while at the same time protecting uncalled for exposure on the pretext of whistleblowing. Whistleblower protection laws have recently been passed in the UK (The Public Interest Disclosure Act, 1999) and in South Africa (Protected Disclosures Act, 2000). In the UK, whistleblowing has been exercised and protected by the law in a range of cases from misappropriation of Box 4.4.2 Information and Atomic Programmes These are extracts from an interview 1 with Arjun Makhijani, president of The Institute for Energy and Environment Research, a US based independent organization which has been given access to the official emission records, including raw data and results of computer modelling of the Los Alamos National Laboratory, an equivalent of India’s Bhabha Atomic Research Centre (BARC). The Indian government has to prove that it follows internationally recognized norms of radiation exposure to the workers and the public. It must allow independent monitoring and make raw data available for scrutiny.... If the government claims that nuclear plants are necessary, then it should acknowledge that there is a price to be paid in terms of health and environment risks. It has to inform the public about the sacrifices involved. On the civilian side, the government has a cavalier attitude, dismissing the well studied evidence about serious birth defects among children born around the Rawatbhata nuclear power plant in Rajasthan.... BARC should disclose how much of the highly radioactive waste generated from the plutonium processing plant is stored there and in what forms. It should also disclose the data from the discharge pipes leading into the bay, as also soil, groundwater and air readings.... if the waste is being taken elsewhere, then there are serious transportation risks involved and the analysis of such risks should be made public.... The use of the Official Secrets Act in preventing public access to data relating to their health is an artifact of British imperialism and should be abandoned. Moreover, there is no reason to keep health and environment data secret. US laws require that such data be made public each year. In the case of the Clean Air Act, the data must be given to the Environment Protection Agency each year, with the nuclear establishment swearing under penalty of perjury that the records are true and complete. In addition, the US has a strong and justiciable freedom of Information Act. 1 Q&A, Times of India, 2001. 88 India Infrastructure Report 2002 funds in homes for the elderly, to exposing inflated expense claims of a Managing Director of a US telecom company, to questioning corporate data on which important government decisions were to be based, to exposure of operational irregularities in big companies.32 In the Indian context of widespread corruption, and dressing up by governments, public bodies, and corporates to give the appearance of fairness, ‘whistleblower protection’ would be vital. GODBOLE’S CRITIQUE Inspite of repeated endeavours from various quarters to change the tone and tenor of the FOI Bill, it seems fated to be passed in its present form. Madhav Godbole, former Union Home Secretary has been following the developments on the proposed legislation ever since the first draft came out in the form of the ‘Shourie draft’. In his critique of the Bill (Godbole 2000), Godbole points out various drawbacks which go towards making the legislation weak. He points out that the preamble itself does not make a clear and unambiguous statement that the law is for enforcing a fundamental right. He also suggests that the title of the Bill should be changed from ‘Freedom of Information Bill’ to ‘Right to Information Bill’. The words ‘consistent with public interest’ in the preamble also limit the application of the Act, as ‘public interest’ is generally construed in favour of government’s interpretation and may quite often mean ‘government’s interest’. He further suggests that the law should cover wider institutions than the ‘state’ in the strict sense of the word. Non-governmental organizations (NGOs), co-operative societies, trusts, professional bodies, and even private companies should be brought within the ambit of the law for disclosure of information. Godbole, like others, also finds the exemption clauses too restrictive. He is also vehemently opposed to class exemptions such as all ‘cabinet papers’, and argues that the revelation of the decision making process of the cabinet does not violate the principle of collective responsibility. Moreover, the committee of secretaries deals with a large number of issues to do with economic management, economic policy, contracts, and tenders, which need not be hidden from the public. Indeed, disclosure would enhance responsibility and judicious discharge of duties. He also makes out a strong case for imposition of fines and penalties for delay in providing information, especially where the information is denied deliberately and knowingly. In toto, the provisions of the Bill read together are a severe disappointment, even leading to the stance from some analysts that it is better to not have a law than to have 32 PCAW (2001). a bad one, as the existing information regime would give sufficient scope for exercising the right which already exists.33 Private Companies Could be Included The provision of infrastructure, whether through public or private bodies, invites an unequivocal application of the right to information to all projects, as they pertain to basic entitlements of the people. Godbole also makes a case for extending the right to information legislation to private companies too: ‘this is particularly relevant in the context of the policies for economic liberalization adopted since the early 1990s and the downsizing of the government envisaged in the coming years. The excessive preoccupation with right to information in the government domain alone is thus misplaced and needs a correction’. In the context of government either contracting out basic services to private enterprise or adopting corporate practices in providing infrastructure, the issue of the people’s right to know takes on an even greater importance. Large contracts must be transparently entered into, and there should be transparency clauses instead of secrecy clauses between government and private parties, in order that dealings take place in an open and fair manner34 (Hindustan Times, 2000). Accepting the irrefutable logic for transparency and sharing of information with stakeholders, private enterprise and multilateral agencies seem to be taking positive action towards implementing the right to information qua stakeholders on their own initiative. WORLD BANK’S PUSH FOR TRANSPARENCY The World Bank, for instance, is taking concrete steps to increase its ambit of information disclosure and is, even now, in the process of reviewing and updating its Disclosure Policy (World Bank 2000). The new proposal recognizes that ‘an approach that goes beyond disclosure to focus on the requirements of the development paradigm would emphasise disseminating relevant information in client countries’. It also emphasizes the need for upgrading of the Bank’s Public Information Centres (PIC), for taking proactive steps to publicize documents like Environment Impact Assessment (EIA) reports in the local language, and engage in actual consultation which goes beyond mere form. It 33 See Rajeev Dhavan, ‘Information Now’, Public Interest Legal Support and Research Centre, New Delhi, mimeo. 34 Hearing a petition asking for a speedy trial of the Howaldtswerke Deutsche Werft AG, Germany (HDW) submarine deals, the High Court of Delhi asked the government to consider having a builtin transparency clause while signing multi-crore multilateral contracts, to avoid the incidence of kickbacks and moneylaundering, which are a drain on the taxpayer. The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 89 suggests the use of information technologies for further outreach. However, the proposals stop short of disclosing certain important documents like the Project Status Reports. In its highway projects, the World Bank has been attempting to build upon the policy of openness and consultations. Although the Strategic Options Study (SOS) for highway projects is prepared on the basis of secondary data, the feasibility study, which consists of looking at indicators as well an economic analysis of all options, is a more consultative process. In the highway project for the Allahabad Bypass, for instance, public consultations on all five options had been carried out. The stakeholders had been informed through advertisements in local newspapers, through the village panchayats and through the district administration. The final choice for the alignment was based on these consultations. Even during the detailed preparation, information was also exchanged between the project authorities and the people, which influenced the design of the project, and the consultation process was completed by sharing the details of the final project with the public. After this, EIA and Rehabilitation Action Plan (RAP) and other policies concerning the rehabilitation of the people were placed in the public domain. This is surely a mark of the changing times, when compared to the total lack of information in the Sardar Sarovar Project (SSP) on the Narmada ten years ago. USING THE RIGHT TO INFORMATION The right to information is only as good as the use to which it is put. And continuous and extensive gives meaning to the information made available. In the US, the Freedom of Information Act has been used creatively to dig into official actions in the sphere of drug manufacture, defence, environment pollution, and hazards of nuclear waste. In Japan, the Act has been used to disclose cases of bloated expenses of officials of the ministry of foreign affairs or ‘financial meetings’ in fictitious restaurants. Health ministries have revealed the additives to drugs with harmful side effects and urban local bodies have been forced to disclose their minutes of meetings. The plea that disclosure would ‘hamper’ the work could not be invoked unless it was supported by substantial proof. Interestingly, in the area of proactive disclosure, some Japanese prefectures (local governments) have gone so far as to publicize the next year’s budget, especially the expected expenditure and inviting citizens’ suggestions. This is in contrast to governments’ usual stance of keeping all aspects of budgets under close wraps on the pretext that the economy will all but fall if anything is given away before the appointed hour. Minutes of meetings in which competing bidders bid for the construction of a museum building have been disclosed. In Korea, information disclosure on economic restructuring has been sought by NGOs and the law is being reviewed to accommodate these requests. THE MKSS EXPERIENCE Indian experience thus far reveals the potency of the right to information in equipping the common person to access information for his possible betterment. The Mazdoor Kisaan Shakti Sangathan (MKSS) have pioneered the call for the right to information from the lowest rung of the hierarchy of both governance, and citizenry––the neglected and poverty ridden villages of India. In using the right to information, the MKSS have evolved a novel method of holding government agents accountable for the fraud perpetrated on the masses in the name of ‘development’. The siphoning of huge amounts of development money intended for developing infrastructure like roads, bridges, water tanks, wells, school buildings, etc. has been brought to light by accessing information from government’s own records and juxtaposing it with the physical reality on the ground. Thus, lakhs of rupees have been ‘spent’ on paper in purchase of material and in payment of wages for construction of ‘invisible’ and non-existent works. The exposure of these documents to the common people who are supposed to have been the beneficiaries of these works or employment schemes has started a virtual movement for accountability, simply articulated as ‘humaara paisa, humaara hisaab’ ––our money, our account. Several years of struggle to get access to information, despite the barrage of resistance from the gram sewaks (clerical staff of the panchayats) right upto the Chief Ministers, has finally begun to concretize into a recognition on the part of both the movement and the government that the process needs to be institutionalized and the right to information cannot be demanded or used merely on the basis of continuous mobilization and informal ‘audits’ by the people. The first victory for the movement was to get a notification under the Panchayat Act that records of all panchayat expenditure could be inspected. The second step was to get a right of photocopying. In 2000, the state of Rajasthan passed a Right to Information Act, which can perhaps be said to be a case of one step forward and two steps backward. For, although the government assured the civil society groups that the development of the law would be a participatory process, the final form of the law left many of the demands unfulfilled in the law. The MKSS’ methodology has been an evolving one, but since its core is very simple, it can, and has, been adapted to different circumstances with some variation. Harsh Mander, a senior bureaucrat and active proponent of the right, has culled out the basics of the methodology of ‘social audit’ and explained the process for the use of right to information by citizens’ groups (Mander and Joshi 1999). 90 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Besides the kind of ‘social audit’ of the type practised by the MKSS35 and other people’s groups, people can use the right to information to monitor the processes of the formal governmental audit and insist on adoption in India of the universally followed practice that audit cannot be satisfied unless local ratepayers are given a hearing and their objections taken on record. Even now, for central government schemes, audit of public works have to be placed before the gram sabhas and completion certificates can be given only after this. The important factor in the creative use of the right to information will be the pressure that stakeholders are able to exert on the institutions that have been hitherto closed and which are in no hurry to open up, legal provisions notwithstanding. The entire exercise will reflect not only on how money is being used, but also on an equally important aspect of how discretion is being exercised. 4.5 COMMUNITY PARTICIPATION MAKES A DIFFERENCE: WATER AND SANITATION PROJECTS IN RURAL INDIA S. Manikutty An important factor contributing to the effectiveness of infrastructure projects is the network of organizations and procedures through which the community (intended beneficiaries) participate in the project at different stages. An approach based on participation by the community takes note of the fact that a substantial portion of the knowledge needed to design and operate a project resides in the community, and this knowledge is crucial for the eventual success of the projects. Besides knowledge, the deeper involvement of community members can highlight possible errors of design and lead to their correction. Bhatt, Manikutty and Mavalankar (1996) studied the factors that facilitate or inhibit community participation (CP) in water and sanitation projects in five states in India, namely Gujarat, Maharashtra, Rajasthan, Karnataka, and Kerala. They also assessed how this participation or lack of it affected the outcomes and functioning of these projects. In all the states studied, the water and sanitation projects were funded by bilateral agencies and incorporated community participation as a mandatory feature. The technologies used varied among the projects: regional piped water supply schemes (Gujarat, Maharashtra, and Kerala); local piped water supply (mini water) schemes (Karnataka); and hand pumps (Karnataka and Rajasthan). At the time of the study (1995), all these projects, except Maharashtra, were in the operation and maintenance (O&M) phase for quite some time (at least five years), but in Maharashtra, the construction phase was not over. The projects were managed in the O&M phase by the State Water Board (Gujarat), local bodies (Karnataka and Rajasthan), and local water institutions in combination with the State Water Board (Kerala). In each of the states, about 12 to 15 villagers were selected (except in Kerala where 27 ‘wards’36 were studied). 35 For a brief description, see Joshi (2000) and Mander and Joshi (1999). 36 Wards in Kerala have about 2500 people, and about 10 wards form a panchayat. In each village, about the five per cent of the village population was interviewed, with a minimum of ten and a maximum of 50 persons in each village. It was ensured that 50 per cent of the respondents were women. A community participation index was developed that would measure the level of participation of each village. Essentially, the community participation was based on intensity (typically measured by the proportions of people) participating in meetings, discussions, decision making, community census, making contributions in cash, kind, and labour, to the project, and in involvement of the daily operations of the facilities. Table 4.5.1 gives the value of CP index for the states covered. Table 4.5.1 Community Participation Index in Certain States State Kerala Maharashtra1 Rajasthan Karnataka Gujarat CP Index (scale of 0–3) 1.80 1.80 1.50 1.45 1.10 Notes: All differences, except that between Kerala and Maharashtra, were statistically significant. 1 In Maharashtra, CP was measured only in the planning and construction phases. FINDINGS Creation of an institutional structure for participation at different stages is important The institutional structure created to elicit and sustain community participation varied among the states studied, and this affected the projects. In Gujarat, though village level water committees called pani panchayats were formed, The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 91 the State Water Board, which was the implementation agency, took little interest in organizing meetings of these committees, or even in listening to their views. Even the role and status of pani panchayats and their relationship with the Water Board were not defined. Thus, the views of the community were not taken into account in the project planning and design. This led to poor utilization of facilitates by the villagers, especially in the case of sanitation. We give here two specific instances. During our study, it was reported that more than 50 per cent of the latrines that were built were not used by the people, since their location in the house made it difficult especially for women to use them. These latrines were converted into store places shortly after they were constructed. In the case of water, the needs of migrating population and their cattle (the needs of cattle were very high) were not taken into account during planning, since the planners missed out this segment altogether. This led to repeated instances of breaking of the pipes by the migrant population to obtain water. In Maharashtra, the institutions to elicit and sustain CP were slow to develop. The Zilla Parishads or ZPs (the district councils) were given the responsibility to develop pani panchayats but they proved to be totally unequal to the task. An outside educational institution (the Tata Institute of Social Sciences, Mumbai (TISS)) was brought in and this agency set up participatory institutions during the planning and early construction phases (the project was still in this phase at the time of our study). TISS tried to train the officials of ZPs, but with no great success (Manikutty 1998: p. 383). In Rajasthan, an NGO, the People’s Education and Development Organization (PEDO), was an intermediary agency entrusted with the planning, design, and construction of facilities (hand pumps and latrines). This NGO had an ideological belief in CP, and it went to great lengths to consult the villagers. It set up an exclusive project organization for this project, and developed participatory mechanisms. It insisted on the people attending meetings, ensured attendance by women, and made it clear that the community was entirely responsible for all the decisions, and saw itself only as a facilitator. Through a programme of education and training, the villagers were made aware of the implications of decisions, so that better decisions could be made. PEDO insisted that all disputes were to be sorted out by the community members themselves, and PEDO refused to give any decision by itself. These meetings, however, were not made into an institutional mechanism, so that once the construction phase was over, and PEDO handed over the facilities to the village panchayats, the participation stopped completely. In Karnataka, the community members were involved in the location of hand pumps. A crucial role was played by the Project Advisory Group (PAG), a group consisting of members from the Karnataka government and DANIDA (Danish International Development Assistance), the bilateral funding agency. The Project Advisory Group was created solely for this project, and this agency put in place a system of participatory rural appraisal (PRA) for location of facilities and for identifying the beneficiaries eligible for different levels of subsidy for latrines. There was, however, lack of clarity regarding how the participation could be sustained once the construction phase was over and PAG was wound up. The community participation in the planning, design, and construction phase was fairly good, mainly with regard to location decisions. However, there were no local institutions set up to continue the participation at the O&M stage; in fact even in the construction phase, participation was minimal. The project became another traditionally administered project by the Zilla Parishads (district councils). Kerala incorporated CP in its project plan and developed a very sound institutional structure to attain and sustain participation. A special organization called socio-economic units (SEUs) was created that was under the Kerala Water Authority (KWA) that implemented this (piped water) scheme, but was funded by the donor agencies. Socioeconomic units had, as their personnel, social scientists who were in charge of development of local participatory institutions. In each village, Ward Water Committees (WWCs) were formed that would be totally responsible for the decisions on the location of water stand posts, health training, and awareness building. Water committee meetings were conducted by the villagers themselves, but SEUs monitored the frequency of the meetings and gave advice when needed. It insisted on regular attendance by the community members; those who did not attend a stipulated number of meetings were excluded from the latrine project. This was justified on the ground that health education was also a part of the project, and hence those who did not learn better health habits were not likely to reap the full benefits from the project. In the construction phase, WWCs were responsible for mobilizing labour contribution (mainly but not solely, for latrine construction), settling disputes, and, to some extent, keeping liaison with engineers of KWA (SEUs also acted as the liaison agent). In the O&M stage, WWCs were responsible for reporting faults, following up the repairs, and doing some (minor) repairs themselves through training and paying a local person. Their roles as well as how their roles differed from those of the other agencies involved were made clear. This was the most elaborate and sustainable institutional structure among all the projects studied. 92 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Institutional Arrangements for Interfacing with Community Members Different mechanisms were used to interface with the community in the different projects. This closely followed the development of the basic institutions themselves. In Gujarat, the only mechanism used was large group meetings with the communities. This was also done in a lackadaisical manner which conveyed the impression that the Water Board was not serious about these meetings. An institution for holding consultations with the villagers on an ongoing basis was not set up at all. In Maharashtra, Rajasthan, and Kerala, a variety of interfacing mechanisms were employed: small group meetings, informal discussions with villagers, training of local people as volunteers in health related information dissemination and involvement in location decisions. In Rajasthan and Kerala, people were trained in proper use of facilities and their upkeep and maintenance. In Kerala, they were also trained in systematically recording faults, reporting them, following them up, and doing quite a lot of repairs themselves. A number of income generation activities such as chlorination of wells were also put in place, which not only provided an income to these people, but also improved the health consciousness of the community members. In Karnataka, there were community meetings and participatory rural appraisal (PRA) sessions to determine the places to locate hand pumps, to decide on who would be eligible for latrine subsidies, and to work out the training sessions in health awareness. Continuous feedback was also obtained from the community regarding the facilities and their use. These mechanisms led to an active and institutionalized interaction with the community by the Zilla Parishads. But these mechanisms were still limited in their scope. Besides, as the onus of running these participatory institutions was left to Zilla Parishads, which had no traditions or expertise to conduct these exercises, and they fell into disuse. Interfacing with Existing Local Institutions Our study shows that existing local institutions could be made use of in W&S projects, provided that these local institutions are strong and are functioning in a reasonable way. Not all the projects did or could interface with these institutions. In Gujarat, there were little contacts with the local institutions. In Karnataka, there were fairly well functioning democratic Zilla Parishads earlier, but these had been dismantled by the government about four years prior to the study. Only the executive wing (consisting of government officials) remained. There were no democratic institutions to which the project institutions could relate and interface with, although the government machinery of the Zilla Parishads was there. Hence the effort was either through a small and inadequate PAG (which was not intended or equipped to take up these responsibilities) or through government officials who had no interest in participation by the community. In Maharashtra, there was an attempt by TISS to involve the Zilla Parishads. The attempt was only moderately successful, due to the limited capacity of TISS to train up the needed personnel and the unenthusiastic people from ZP who were to be trained. In Rajasthan, again, no attempt was made by PEDO to build on the existing local institutions. The result was that after PEDO withdrew from the project (after the construction phase), there was no mechanism at all for the community to interface with the local institutions. In Kerala, we see the most effective interface between local institutions and project institutions. Kerala had a well functioning panchayat system. SEUs were organized at three levels: the state level unit; one for each of the three zones– –northern, central, and southern; and at all village panchayats. The SEU at the state level was a unit of KWA and also developed close linkages with other bodies such as the Ministry of Rural Development. The socio-economic units at the zonal level developed links with the district level bodies. Panchayat Water Committees were formed at the panchayat level and consisted of all the elected panchayat members and representatives of local organizations. At the ward level, Ward Water Committees (WWCs) were formed. The elected ward member to the panchayat was the chairperson of a WWC, and there were representatives from local grassroot organizations and social workers in the area. At least two of these representatives had to be women. This structure ensured that the WWCs would be the main grass-root unit for generating and sustaining participation. The higher level committees served to deal with problems that could not be dealt with at the ward level. The presence of elected members and the insistence by SEUs on regular and open meetings in which decisions were taken, ensured that potential conflicts could be resolved efficiently. The political clout of panchayat members could be brought to bear upon KWA to expedite construction and ensure satisfactory maintenance. IMPACT ON PROJECT OUTCOMES Our concern was not with CP per se but its influence on project outcomes. Hence, we measured the outcomes of the five projects along different dimensions such as technological outcomes, health outcomes, satisfaction of beneficiaries, use of the facilities provided by the project, etc. We found that due to a number of other factors affecting outcomes, a direct correlation of outcomes to CP did not yield any The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 93 results. For example, the percentage of facilities working depended on the technology of the projects (hand pumps, for example, were more prone to breakdowns than water taps from a piped water supply). The satisfaction of users depended on how badly they needed the services to begin with, and changes in habits depended on the initial levels of literacy. Hence we studied two projects, both piped water schemes, in adjoining districts in Kerala, both with similar terrain and with similar demographic and hydrological characteristics as well. Two villages, one in each of the two project areas, were studied. The two villages studied were within five kilometers of one another, although they belonged to different districts. One of the districts was in the project earlier studied and had significant CP while the other was delivered by the KWA in the traditional manner with no involvement from community. In terms of outcomes, the two projects were strikingly different, as may be seen from Table 4.5.2. In the village with CP, supplied water quality was not only perceived to be better, but was indeed actually so, as we checked out ourselves. Respondents in the Project II village stated that the pipes in many places had rusted but no corrective measures were taken. On the other hand, in Project I, the respondents stated they had got the pipes replaced whenever there was a problem. In the Project II village, there were no records anywhere in the community to show how many taps were out of order; while in the Project I village, there was not only such a record, but also records of the follow up. The involvement of community members can also be seen from the responses to the question of responsibility if taps went defective. The typical response of the villagers in Project I was: ‘It is our responsibility. Any of us going to the town would follow it up’, whereas in Project II, the typical response was: ‘It is KWA’s responsibility to keep the taps working. It is not our job to follow it up’. The projects aimed at supplying treated, safe drinking water as a means of improving the health habits. But Project I had a programme of health education, in which the community members not only attended, but also contributed by mobilizing community members to attend classes and conducting classes themselves. Some were trained in the chlorination of wells so that this traditional source also would be safe for drinking. The Project II village had no such programmes. In Table 4.5.2, we note the differences in the usage of the treated water from the source as being much higher than in Project II, in which the community members continued to use also the traditional sources. These continued to be unsafe due to lack of any chlorination programes. Table 4.5.2 Outcomes With and Without CP (percentage) Project I in village with CP Perception of quality of water: 1 Percentage of taps working2 Respondents using only piped water for drinking* Respondents using only piped water for cooking* Respondents’ perception of responsibility for keeping the area near the stand posts clean Those who use it* Government** Caretaker3 Responsibility to set right faults The community members2 The agency (‘We shall not take any action’)2 No response/do not know** Initiative taken in the past to report defects2 Per cent of respondents satisfied with the project2 Per cent of respondents dissatisfied with the project2 1 2 3 ‘Satisfactory’: 40 ‘Good’ : 60 Project II in village without CP 92 39 40 ‘Brackish’: 25 ‘Muddy’: 25 ‘Unclean’: 50 74 25 27 26 9 23 66 0 34 48 26 0 18 63 19 95 75 10 0 30 40 In both villages, 80 people were interviewed. Figures in percentages. denotes the difference being significant at 0.01 level; * at 0.05 level; ** at 0.1 level. The difference was mainly due to non-existence of a caretaker and hence not statistically tested. Source: Manikutty (1997). 94 India Infrastructure Report 2002 The project I village had, from the very beginning, insisted upon the community members taking responsibility for not only keeping the stand posts in working condition, but also keeping the surrounding areas clean. The Project II village did nothing of the kind. The appearance of stand posts in the two project areas studied was strikingly different: while the stand posts in Project I area were scrupulously clean (kept clean by the community members), those in the Project II areas by and large presented a pathetic appearance, with the surrounding areas filthy and unhygienic. When questioned, the community members in the Project II areas did not feel it was their problem. The Project I village evolved participatory mechanisms at every stage. Further, it also put in place an institutional structure to make the participation effective and sustainable, through building a set of institutions and devising institutional mechanisms and processes, as we have seen. The Project II village, on the other hand, saw the project as a purely technological exercise of building pipes and stand posts, and no other institution except the engineering department of the government was involved. The difference in the outcomes studied above are striking, and serves to underline the role community participation plays in infrastructure projects. Application To Other Infrastructure Projects The lessons learned with regard to the W&S projects may be applicable in other infrastructure projects as well. For example, the problem of locating a village telephone is conceptually similar to locating a water tap. More important is the notion that an appropriate institutional structure is needed to implement infrastructure. For example, formation of users committees, with strong incentives for people to take part in their decision making, linking them with existing institutions are all steps that can lead to better implementation of these projects. The role that democratic local institutions play in the effectiveness of infrastructure projects cannot be overemphasized. Though lip service is being paid to the development of institutions such as gram panchayats, the fact seems to be that there is really no commitment on the part of the top, either in the political or bureaucratic system, to make these institutions meaningful and effective37. CONCLUSION Considerable knowledge resides in the communities and it is necessary to build on this knowledge. Otherwise, vital inputs may get mixed out. Commitment from communities is also essential for the sustainability of projects. They help to reduce monitoring, supervision, and maintenance costs besides ensuring appropriate design. However, participation cannot be taken for granted. It will not come about through statements of intent in project documents. It will come about and will be sustainable only if appropriate institutions like empowered panchayats and others are built or allowed to exist. REFERENCES Balakrishnan, S. and S. Sekhar (1998), Public Services and the Urban Poor in Mumbai: A Report Card, Public Affairs Centre, Bangalore. Bhatt, A., Manikutty, S., and D. Mavalankar (1996), Community Participation in Rural Drinking Water and Sanitation Projects, The World Bank, New Delhi. Calabresi, Guido and Douglas A. Melamed (1972), ‘Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral’, Harvard Law Review, Vol. 85, 1089–128. Coase, R.H. (1960), ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, The Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 3, 1–44. Dreze, Jean and Amartya Sen (1999), ‘Public Action and Social Inequality’, in Barbara Harriss-White and Sunil Subramanian (eds), Illfare in India: Essays on India’s Social Sector in Honor of S. Guhan, Sage Publications, New Delhi. Godbole, Madhav (2000), ‘A Right to Information: A Long Way to Go’, National Centre for Advocacy Studies. Gopakumar, K. (1997), ‘Public Feedback as an Aid to Public Accountability: Reflections on an Innovative Approach’, Public Administration and Development, Vol. 17, 281–2. Goldberg, V. (1976), ‘Regulation and Administered Contracts’, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 7 (Autumn), 426–52. Hindustan Times, 5 September 2000. India Today (2000), ‘Future Vision: Ideas for India’, 31 January. Jain, Rekha (2001), ‘A Review of the Indian Telecom Sector’, in 3iNetwork (2001). Joshi, Piyush (2001), Law Relating to Infrastructure Projects, Butterworths India, New Delhi. Kaplow, Louis and Steven Shavell, (1996), ‘Property Rules versus Liability Rules: An Economic Analysis’, Harvard Law Review, Vol. 109, 713–90. Mander, Harsh and Abha Joshi (1999), ‘The Right to Information Movement in India: People’s Power for the Control of Corruption,’ Commonwealth Human Rights Initiative, New Delhi. Manikutty, S. (1997), ‘Community Participation: So What? Evidence from a Comparative Study of Two Rural Water Supply and Sanitation Projects in India’, Development Policy Review, Vol. 15, No. 2, 115–40. Manikutty, S. (1998), ‘Community Participation: Lessons from Five Water and Sanitation Projects in India’, Development Policy Review, Vol. 16, No. 4, 373–404. 37 See for instance, Nanavaty (2000) in the IIR 2001, Section 9.4. See also a discussion of failure of decentralization in India in Chapter 2 in this report. The Constitutional and Legal Framework for Governance 95 McCubbins, Mathew D., Roger G. Noll and Barry R. Weingast (1987), ‘Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control’, Journal of Law Economics and Organization, Vol. 3, 240–60. Mohan, R. (2000), ‘Achieving Higher Economic Growth’, L.B. Himatsingha Memorial Lecture, Guwahati. Nanavaty, Anish (2001), ‘Implications of the 74th Amendment of Water and Wastewater’, in 3iNetwork (2001). 3iNetwork (2001), India Infrastructure Report 2001, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Ostrom, Elinor, Larry Schroeder, and Susan Wynne (1993), Institutional Incentives and Sustainable Development, West View Press, Boulder. Paul, Samuel (1995a), Strengthening Public Accountability: New Approaches and Mechanisms, Public Affairs Centre, Bangalore. —— (1995b), A Report Card on Public Services in Indian Cities: A View from Below, Public Affairs Centre, Bangalore. —— (1998), Making Voice Work: The Report Card on Bangalore’s Public Service, Policy Research Working Paper, No. 1921, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Paul, S. and S. Sekhar (1999), The Second Report Card on Bangalore’s Public Services, Public Affairs Centre, Bangalore. Paul, S., Shiela Premkumar and Prasann Thatte (2000), Wanted: An Enabling Industrial Environment in Karnataka, Public Affairs Centre, Bangalore. PCAW (2001), Policy into Practice: A Review of the Activities of Public Concern at Work at the Millennium, Public Concern At Work, London. Ray, Debraj and Arunava Sen (1992), ‘Economic Theory of Quantity Controls’, in Kaushik Basu and Pulin Nayak (eds), Development Policy and Economic Theory, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Ray, Debraj and Arunava Sen (1994), ‘Price and Quantity Controls: A Survey of Some Major Issues’, in Bhaskar Dutta (ed.), Welfare Economics, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. RBI (2001), Report of the Advisory Group on Bankruptcy Law (2001), Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Spiller, Pablo T. and Ingo Vogelsang (1996), ‘The United Kingdom: A Pacesetter in Regulatory Incentives’, in Brian Levy and Pablo T. Spiller (eds), Regulations, Institutions and Commitment, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Smith, Warrick (1997), ‘Utility Regulators: Roles and Responsibilities’, Public Policy for the Private Sector, Note 128, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Weitzman, M. (1974), ‘Prices versus Quantities’, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 41, 477–91. Williamson, Oliver E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, The Free Press, New York. World Bank (1997), India: New Directions in Health Sector Development at the State Level, Washington, D.C. —— (2000), ‘World Bank Policy on Information Disclosure’, Discussion Draft, Washington, D.C. Upp, S. (1995), Making the Grade: A Guide to Implement the Report Card Methodology, Public Affairs Centre, Bangalore. 96 India Infrastructure Report 2002 5 ENVIRONMENT AND REHABILITATION 5.1 ENVIRONMENTAL GOVERNANCE AND REGULATION IN INDIA Atiyah Curmally LEGISLATIVE EFFORTS Legislative efforts at pollution control in India date back to the mid-nineteenth century.1 Many of these Acts dealt with environmental regulation in a piecemeal manner and proved ineffective at reducing the levels of pollution. Action against polluters had necessarily to be initiated in courts by those affected. Pollution and environmental degradation were addressed very generally in terms of nuisance, negligence, liability, and a few principles of tort law. The spate of legislations2 in the post-independence period also dealt only incidentally with pollution. Both air and water pollution continued to increase. Perhaps inspired by the Stockholm Declaration of 1972, the Water (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act, 1974 (the Water Act), provided for the institutionalization of pollution control machinery by establishing Boards for prevention and control of pollution of water. These Boards were entitled to initiate proceedings against infringement of environmental law, without waiting for the affected people to launch legal action. The Water Cess Act, 1977, supplemented the Water Act by requiring specified industries to pay cess on their water consumption. With the passing 1 The Shore Nuisance Act, 1853, the Indian Penal Act, 1860, the Indian Easement Act, 1882, the Bengal Smoke Nuisance Act, 1905, the Bombay Smoke Nuisance Act, 1912, and the Motor Vehicles Act, 1939 were some of the pioneering legislative attempts. 2 These included the Factories Act, 1948, the Industries (Development and Regulation) Act, 1951, the River Boards Act, 1956, the Atomic Energy Act, 1962, the Insecticides Act, 1968, the Merchant Shipping (Amendment) Act, 1970, and the Radiation Protection Rules, 1971. of the Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act, 1981 (the Air Act), the need was felt for an integrated approach to pollution control. The Water Pollution Control Boards were authorized to deal with air pollution as well, and became the Central Pollution Control Board (CPCB) and the State Pollution Control Boards (SPCBs). The Bhopal Gas leak disaster of December 1984 precipitated the tightening of environmental regulation. In 1985, the Department of Environment was changed to the Ministry of Environment and Forests (MoEF) and given greater powers. The Environment (Protection) Act, 1986 (EPA), was passed, to act as an umbrella legislation. The Act also vested powers with the central government to take all measures to control pollution and protect the environment. The Environment (Protection) Rules, 1986 were subsequently notified to facilitate exercise of the powers conferred on the Boards by the Act. The EPA identifies the MoEF as the apex policy making body in the field of environment protection. The MoEF acts through the CPCB and the SPCBs. The CPCB is a statutory organization and the nodal agency for pollution control. The EPA in 1986 and the amendments to the Air and Water Acts in 1987 and 1988 furthered the ambit of the Boards’ functions. Constitutional Directives In terms of constitutional provisions, the 42nd Amendment of 1976 for the first time imposed an obligation on the part of the state (Article 48A) and the citizens (Article 51A(g)) to endeavour to protect and improve the environment and to safeguard the forests and wildlife of the country. The economic reforms of 1991, the Rio Conference of 1992, Environment and Rehabilitation and growing environmental awareness all resulted in further amendments to the constitution. Role of the Judiciary The Supreme Court and High Courts have played an active role in the enforcement of constitutional provisions and legislations relating to environmental protection. The fundamental right to life and personal liberty enshrined in Article 21 of the Constitution has been interpreted by the courts to include the right to pollution-free air and water.3 Also, relaxing the enforcement of strict rules of proof and modification of the traditional rule of standing (locus standi) so as to facilitate public interest litigations has served, more or less, to remove the difficulty in individuals approaching courts for redressal. The backdrop of all this has been the growing environmental awareness among the public. This has been demonstrated by public demonstrations and protests throughout the 1970s and 1980s4, growth in environment and development oriented non-governmental organizations (NGOs), citizen groups, and pressure groups in India (today, roughly 20 times the size in 1985), and the increase in the frequency of public interest litigations. Working of Environmental Regulation An analysis of the principal pollution control legislations, the Air and Water Acts, reveals that these legislations are mostly punitive in nature. The Pollition Control Boards (PCBs) have thus restricted their approach to pollution control to ‘Command and Control’ (CAC). This implies that the state agencies are to function as watchdogs to keep an eye on the existing industries. All new industries, before they start to function, would in this approach require prior permission to do so. The agency responsible then permits them to carry out industrial activity, subject to certain terms and conditions. While the basic functions of the CPCB remain prevention, control, and abatement of air and water pollution, with the various SPCBs assuming these functions, the role of the CPCB is restricted to providing technical or scientific assistance. The CPCB has maintained the major role of prescribing the standard limits for various pollutants. While the SPCBs may prescribe stricter limits if they choose, they may not dilute the standards stipulated by the CPCB. The SPCBs employ three instruments, namely, consent to establish producing units, consent to operate, and 3 Subhash Kumar vs. State of Bihar AIR 1991 SC 420, 424; M.C. Mehta vs. Union of India 1992 (3) SCC 256, 257; and Virender Gaur vs. State of Haryana 1995 (2) SCC 577, 581. 4 The ‘Chipko Movement’ was in protest against the alienation of traditional rights of users to forests, and the exploitation of timber by the forest departments. 97 standards for air and water pollution. Under the Water Act, consent is necessary for an industry to ‘discharge effluent into a stream’. Under the Air Act, consent is necessary to ‘establish or operate an industrial plant in an air pollution control area’. The other functions of the SPCBs are advising the state governments, formulation of preventive methods, technology development, regulation of location of industries, disposal of hazardous wastes, and collection and dissemination of information on the prevention and control of pollution. The PCBs also have the power to move court for ‘restraining apprehended pollution’ as a preventive measure (Section 33 of the Water Act and Section 22A of the Air Act). In an extreme case, a PCB can give ‘directions to any person, officer or authority’ in the interest of pollution control, which ‘includes the power to direct closure, prohibition or regulation of any industry or process, or stoppage or regulation of supply of electricity, water or any other service’ (Section 33A of the Water Act and Section 31A of the Air Act). Failure to obtain consent and violation of consent conditions makes the occupier of an industrial unit liable for punishment under both Acts. The punishment prescribed is imprisonment with unlimited fine. For minor violations of the Acts, such as failure to provide information, obstructing personnel of the Board from discharging their duties, and so forth, the penalty prescribed is imprisonment upto three months or fine of Rs 10,000 or both. More severe punishments are provided under both Acts for continued violation after the first conviction (Section 41 to 45A of the Water Act and Section 37 to 39 of the Air Act). Thus, the role of the Boards is mostly that of an enforcer, and the primary functional tool employed by them for controlling industrial pollution is inspection of polluting units. The Water Act prohibits the discharge of pollutants into water bodies beyond established standards (Section 24), and requires that generators of all new and existing sources of discharge into water bodies get the prior consent of the PCBs (Section 25 and 26 respectively). It also lays down penalties, such as fines and imprisonment, for not complying with these (and other) regulations of the Act. Prior to 1988, enforcement was through criminal prosecution initiated by State Boards and by seeking injunctions to restrain polluters. After amendments to the Act in 1988, the Boards were given more teeth—they can now close errant factories or cut off their water or electricity by an administrative order. The ‘command’ therefore is the stipulation of certain upper limits of parameters, while the ‘control’ is the power to withdraw the power supply, water supply, and the imposition of the penalty (fines, imprisonment). Concern has been expressed that the existing pollution control laws are not backed by sound policy pronouncements 98 India Infrastructure Report 2002 and even when they are, it is more as an afterthought rather than as clearly formulated guiding principles. For example, neither the preamble nor the provisions of the Water Act or Air Act provide much concrete policy guidance. The Acts focus more on procedural details like setting up of the CPCB and SPCBs, their constitution, structure, powers and functions. It is only in the list of powers of the State Board under the Water Act that one finds any hint that the legislators understood that there might be costs to balance against the benefits of pollution control: ‘the Boards are to evolve economical and reliable methods of treatment of trade effluents’.5 Even the rules6 issued under these Acts focus almost wholly on procedural matters. These rules illustrate the forms to be filled out by the Central Board for its annual report, list the fees for particular pollution tests, and give sample application forms for consent orders without describing how to make use of the information provided. Nowhere do the rules take advantage of the power granted to assist and guide SPCBs to promulgate substantive rules with policy import. As a result, policies exist without laws, laws without policies, and there have even been cases where policies have followed legislation. As late as 1992, nearly two decades after the enactment of the Water Act, the Government of India (GOI) came out with a Policy Statement for Abatement of Pollution. Some incongruencies that come to light are the following. The statement emphasizes ‘promoting technological inputs to reduce industrial pollution’. However, it fails to assign the agencies responsible for this task. As of now, the function of PCBs extends to the granting of consent and implementing standards. They are not in any position to offer technical advice required by industry. Further, though ‘public cooperation in securing a clean environment’ finds mention in the policy statement, no legislation has evolved incorporating this even a decade after the policy pronouncement. Pollution control laws have neither kept pace with constitutional directives, nor have they operationalized the space that exists for popular participation if these directives are truly understood. Environmental legislations, such as the Air and Water Acts, on the contrary, have a strong centralizing tendency, with the state and Central government as the exclusive decision makers. Further, none of these laws provide for co-ordinated functioning of the various enforcement agencies with the third tier of governance— panchayats and municipalities. There is nothing at all to involve local communities. 5 Water (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act, 1974, Section 17(1)(h). 6 The Water (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Rules, 1975; The Water (Prevention and Control of Pollution) (Procedure for Transaction of Business) Rules, 1975; The Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Rules, 1982; The Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) (Union Territories) Rules, 1983. As a result, the activist role played by the higher judiciary has been on the rise. This has included issuance of administrative orders to the extent that the courts have been forced to catalyze the legislature to codify certain legislations. For example, the Public Liability Insurance Act, enacted in 1991,7 fixed the liability on the occupier of an industrial unit for the damage caused to a third party. This was the legislative version of the judicial pronouncement of the Supreme Court in the Delhi Oleum Gas Leak Case.8 THE PREVAILING FORM OF GOVERNANCE From the characteristics of the pollution control mechanism in place in India, it can be gleaned that there exists a command and control regime with a set of laws designed to perform a preventive rather than a proactive role. Even the constitutional provisions, while affirming the right of the State and the duties of the citizens, do so without upholding the corresponding rights of the individuals and the duties of the state. In other words, citizens cannot claim environmental protection as a right and the state is not bound by any duties to protect the environment. It becomes evident that environmental policy and law in India has not evolved in anticipation of a problem, but rather has been a knee jerk reaction to existing problems.9 Judging by the prohibitive levels of pollution in existence today it has been ill equipped to achieve any of the targets specified. The EPA, for example, came into existence to deal with all anticipated environmental problems with the hope that mass disasters of the Bhopal variety are prevented from recurring. In over a decade of its working, no evidence exists, both in its content and application, that this law has the potential to meet the challenges of mass environmental disasters. Central and state governments and the CPCB and SPCBs have adopted a soft attitude towards polluting industries and have done little more than issue warnings. The result is that these laws are practised more in violation than conformity and a large number of industries operate without proper safety and pollution control measures.10 For successful implementation of the CAC policy envisaged, certain facilities are of paramount importance. These are infrastructure of the regulatory agencies, a thorough understanding of environmental problems, and most importantly the monitoring and enforcement 7 An Act to provide for public liability insurance for the purpose of providing immediate relief to persons affected by an accident occurring while handling any hazardous substance. 8 M.C. Mehta vs. Union of India AIR 1987 SC 982. 9 It may have also arisen out of elitist concerns, and not the concerns of those actually affected. Thus, they are overly ambitious on paper but lack effective deterrents and are inadequately implemented. 10 Parikh, Parikh, Tata and Laxmi (1999), p. 15. Environment and Rehabilitation capabilities of the regulatory agencies.11 An evaluation of the PCBs, however, reveals that their working is rife with shortcomings. Enforcement The primary functional tool employed by the PCBs for controlling industrial pollution is inspection of polluting units. Given the penalties in force for non-compliance in India and keeping in mind the extent of the SPCBs’ powers, the impact of inspections on compliance is only as strong as the threat of enforcement and punishment faced by the industrial units. Studies conducted reveal that there appears to be no impact of inspections on emissions.12 The reality is that environmental management often degenerates into crisis management. Inspections are undertaken at the time that operating consent is granted and thereafter usually only in response to complaints, accidents, or other emergencies. Enforcement by the PCBs, as a result, is woefully inadequate. Further, a study conducted by the Planning Commission found that they do not have a complete inventory of polluting and potentially polluting industries. Small industries (capable of high levels of pollution) have been left out of the purview, further undermining efforts at pollution control. Small industries are known to contribute as much as 40 per cent of air and water pollution. Monitoring Monitoring conducted by the PCBs is also far from effective. Polluting industries may make a one-time investment and set up Effluent Treatment Plants (ETPs). Around 2–5 per cent of its capital investment may be so spent on pollution control. The costs of operating these facilities are anywhere between 15–30 per cent of the investment made, annually.13 As operating costs are high, industries are often reluctant to run these plants. Poor monitoring almost always allows units to get away without operating these plants properly. The PCBs claim that inadequate manpower limits their monitoring. Poorly Staffed The Planning Commission study revealed that the PCBs are very poorly staffed. The study highlighted the predominance of non-technical members in most of the Boards, the lack of professionals in the composition of the Boards, and also the tendency to not fill vacancies of members representing local bodies. Thus, both motivationally and in ability, the PCBs are ill-structured. 11 To be effective, CAC with ambitious targets, would include much cost, and steep punitive measures. 12 Pargal et al. (1997), p. 16. 13 Parikh, Parikh and Tata (1999), p. 10. 99 Lack Technical Skills One of the resons for ineffective monitoring is the lack of technical skills of the PCBs. For instance, the Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling) Rules, 1998 specify the working of incinerators so as to reduce emissions of toxins like furans and dioxins. However, neither the CPCB nor the SPCBs have the capacity to even collect samples, let alone analyse these toxins. Inadequate Funding The principal sources of funding for PCBs are government grants and revenue collected under the Water Cess Act. In actual fact, PCBs are starved for funds. The result is inadequate infrastructure in terms of laboratories, monitoring equipment, and regional offices, inadequate staff, both technical and administrative, and an inability to discharge their primary functions. For example, the Bihar Pollution Control Board (BPCB), which administers pollution laws in the second most populous state of the country, has continuously been deprived of funds. For several years, the state government withheld funding, restricting BPCB expenditure to less than a third of its modest requisition. Even ten years after the enactment of the Water Act, the BPCB did not have a single laboratory or analyst to test effluent samples.14 A subset of the issue of inadequate funding is the manner in which the SPCBs have made expenses. An analysis of the expenditure incurred by the SPCBs during the Eighth Five Year Plan shows that the primary expenditure was on administration amounting to 57 per cent. The ratio of capital expenditure to total expenditure was about 14 per cent. Maintenance, depreciation, and other expenses constituted the major chunk of the remaining part. It follows that expenditure on pollution prevention activities, training, and research and development was for all practical purposes negligible. Lack of Willingness to Implement Policy A lack of willingness to implement policy is also apparent. While the PCBs have the authority to cut off the electricity and water supplies of polluting industries, launch prosecutions, and initiate proceedings against top management so as to hold them personally liable, the use of these measures has been meagre. With hardly any local representation inclusive of people who are affected, this is almost inevitable. In addition, they have failed to bring the offenders to book. For example, in Rajasthan only two convictions have been obtained, despite nearly 7000 cases cases filed in court against air and water polluters.15 14 15 Divan and Rosencranz (2001), p. 3. Parikh, Parikh and Tata (1999), p. 13. 100 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Political Interference However, the argument is made that PCBs are, sometimes, not able to exercise powers to force compliance because of interference from powerful interest and pressure groups. Such interference is sometimes based on the argument that strict compliance with standards will lead to closure of industrial units, which in turn may result in unemployment and protests. This interference is hardly surprising given that often the Boards are represented by vested interests responsible for pollution. With the position of the Chairman of the Boards invariably being a political appointee, political interference is rampant, and internal sabotage of most cases is then almost inevitable. Variations in Enforcement The high degree of political interference may be one of the factors responsible for wide variations in enforcement across states. It has been argued that although states cannot compete by lowering environmental standards in order to attract new investment, they can get around this by lax enforcement.16 This could be the outcome of a so-called ‘race to the bottom’ for environmental quality in which states invariably sacrifice the environment in the competition for jobs and economic growth. For example, there exists no uniform procedure for the grant of consents under the Air and Water Acts. Some SPCBs grant consents for a fixed period, usually between 1 and 3 years while the others may issue open-ended consents. The consent fee structure and industry classifications also differ widely across States, suggesting inequitable horizontal treatment of industrial units. For instance, if an industrial unit falling in the investment limit between Rs 50 lakhs and Rs 100 lakhs applies for consent from the Madhya Pradesh Pollution Control Board, it is bound to pay Rs 7500 as fees whereas if the same unit applied for consent from the Kerala Pollution Control Board, the fee would be Rs 2000. Nonfilling of the sanctioned strength is one of the factors behind widely varying per unit staff ratios across SPCBs. In Andhra Pradesh, one technical person has to monitor 100 units whereas Kerala and Himachal Pradesh have 14 and 12 persons respectively for the same task. The norms for determining the staffing pattern of the boards have not been prescribed, leading to wide differences in the per polluting unit availability of staff for monitoring.17 PERVERSE INCENTIVES UNDER CAC Consent from the PCB is necessary before any industry is set up. After the consent, the industry is supposed to maintain 16 Gupta (1996). 17 Evaluation Study on the Functioning of State Pollution Control Boards, Programme Evaluation Organization, Planning Commission. the characteristics under the prescribed norms. This approach permits little flexibility in the means of achieving goals as it forces all firms to make similar efforts to control pollution. As the standards are source-specific, being neither either technology based or performance based, this policy gives little incentive to polluters to search for cleaner technologies or improved abatement technologies. Another drawback is the inability to take advantage of the economic efficiency possible in pollution control. While standards with strict implementation may limit emissions of pollutants, they typically exact relatively high costs in the process, by forcing firms to resort to unduly expensive means of controlling pollution. On the governments’ side, they impose high monitoring costs. As the marginal abatement costs vary among firms, the appropriate technology in one situation may not be as cost-effective as in another. The penalties for non-compliance with standards are unrelated to the compliance costs. The prosecution and court decisions are based on compliance or non-compliance and not on the extent of compliance. The fines are prescribed in nominal terms and are independent of the quantity and quality of emissions. The ambient and source standards are laid down independently, unrelated in terms of the volume of pollution generation activities. As a result, it is quite conceivable that the quality of the environment could continue to deteriorate even with a high degree of compliance. For example, according to the standards stipulated regarding the ambient air quality, five parameters are chosen. If in the analytical reports of ambient air quality, these five parameters are under limits, the ambient air is deemed fit for human consumption. If this indeed were so there would be no phenomenal rise in respiratory problems.18 Command and Control approaches are inefficient for the regulatory agency as well, as detailed information about production processes and various pollution control devices is required before setting standards. With diverse industries, it becomes expensive and time consuming to obtain the necessary information of each industry. The Minimum National Discharge Standards,19 for example, have been established to enforce industrial discharges. Set at levels at or near the maximum effluent reduction technically achievable, they are in general economically unrealistic and technically unfeasible. In the face of such standards dictated by the CPCB, the SPCBs are forced into an inflexible position in which the only two alternatives they have are ordering non-compliant industries to close or not enforcing the standards at all (if they are serious about implementation). 18 19 Brandon et al. (1995), p. 5. Environment (Protection) Rules, 1986 (Schedules I and VI) respectively. Environment and Rehabilitation 101 As a result of these prohibitively high standards it was found that a significant proportion of units discharging trade effluents into water streams do not have treatment plants in the states of Assam, Tamil Nadu, Punjab, Kerala, Karnataka, Gujarat, and Haryana. Similarly, a considerable proportion of units emitting air pollutants do not have any air pollution control measures in the states of Punjab, Assam, Bihar, Gujarat, Karnataka and Kerala.20 This inflexibility often results in protracted negotiations and even litigation with considerable costs involved. Cost-effectiveness is further hampered by the fact that standards do not take into consideration factors such as carrying capacity of the environment. Stipulations for standards can be broadly divided into cumulative parameters and specific parameters. Our laws stress cumulative parameters rather than specific parameters. Many studies have shown that certain pollutants have the capacity of bioaccumulation. As the number of industries obtaining consent is on the increase, the pollution load on the ecosystem is getting heavier by the day. As a result the carrying capacity at some places has long been crossed. The existence of more than one set of standards presents a lack of clarity. For example, the Environment (Protection) Rules prescribe industry specific standards and national minimum standards.21 The industry specific standards in Schedule I are restricted to only select parameters and are not necessarily exhaustive. The Schedule VI standards apply to all industrial units for which specific norms are not published in Schedule I. However it is not clear if the minimum national standards in respect of other parameters apply to the industries specified in Schedule I. Consequently, the adoption of different standards remains within the wide discretionary powers of the PCBs. Since the stipulation of standards by the regulatory authorities there has been no revision in upper limits or enforcement of stricter limits. Neither has any mechanism evolved to permit the PCBs to review the same at regular intervals. In terms of court-driven implementation of pollution control measures, on several occasions both the High Courts22 and the Supreme Court23 have admonished the PCBs for failing to implement pollution control laws. In 20 Evaluation Study on the Functioning of State Pollution Control Boards, Programme Evaluation Organization, Planning Commission. 21 Environment (Protection) Rules, 1986 (Schedule I, Schedule II, Schedule III). 22 Bayer (India) Ltd. vs. State of Maharashtra 1994 (4) BOM.C.REP. 309, 330; Pravinbhai Patel vs. State of Gujarat 1995 (2) GUJ.L.R. 1210, 1234; V. Lakshmipathy vs. State of Karnataka AIR 1992 KAR 57, 70; Suo Motu vs. Vatva Industries Association AIR 2000 GUJ 33, 35. 23 M.C. Mehta vs. Union of India 1998 (3) SCALE 602 and 1998 (4) SCALE 326. the Ganga Pollution Case,24 the Supreme Court emphasized that notwithstanding the comprehensive provisions contained in the Water Act, the State Boards had not taken effective steps to prevent the discharge of effluents into the river. The court further observed that when statutory authorities do not discharge their duties then the courts had the power to issue appropriate direction. Further, the Delhi Oleum Gas Leak Case can be used to demonstrate the role played by the courts in plugging lacunae in the existing legislation. The Air and Water Acts do not have any provision for compensation to those affected by pollution. This judgement widened the scope of Article 21 by lying down that the power of the Supreme Court includes the power to award compensation. But this model of ad hoc court-driven environmental law enforcement raises severe problems. The appropriateness and suitability of courts of law in deciding matters that require technical expertise is questionable. The Indian judiciary has little technical expertise. Further, long delays in delivering judgements are more the norm. There is no viable alternative dispute settlement or conciliation mechanism either. SUGGESTIONS REGULATION TO FACILITATE MORE EFFECTIVE Every pollution control law ought to be preceded by clear policy pronouncements. The laws enacted ought to incorporate the policy and worry about appropriate mechanisms for implementation. Codification and consolidation of pollution control laws, that do away with the overlaps is needed. Laws ought to be enforced within a clear time-bound frame and administrative accountability ought to be ensured. However, a country’s institutional capacity to implement and enforce environmental governance is a key consideration. Monitoring and enforcement pose huge pitfalls for the regulatory agencies in India. Inspite of the potential cost of non-compliance to industries being not trivial (in terms of the penalties imposed), compliance is weak. The suggestions made below to facilitate better regulation take into account the weaknesses of the regulatory agencies, especially in terms of monitoring and enforcement. Regulatory Approaches While regulatory approaches are the most popular approach to environmental problems, favoured by policy makers because of the certainty of outcome they offer, they are also the most costly in terms of monitoring and enforcement. Nevertheless, in some cases these are the only feasible 24 M.C. Mehta vs. Union of India, AIR, 1988, SC, 1037. 102 India Infrastructure Report 2002 instruments by which to achieve the aims of public policy. For example, controlling emissions of hazardous substances will generally best be accomplished by outright bans. Similarly, land zoning regulations are the most effective means to ensure that residential areas are not downstream or downwind from polluting factories. In such cases, strict implementation of the laws and credibility of the sanctions imposed must be ensured to make sure that regulations are effective. Combination of Approaches: Some regulatory approaches are more efficient than others. One that is particularly inefficient is to stipulate abatement technologies—this tends to discourage innovations that have the potential to limit pollution emissions more cheaply. In such cases, the use of a combination of approaches may be a better alternative. For example, in Malaysia, a combination of standards and charges has been effective in reducing water pollution from palm oil mills. After being given one year to install treatment facilities, palm oil mills were required to reduce their wastewater discharges, taking biological oxygen demand (BOD) concentration as the key parameter. Progressively stringent effluent standards were implemented in four stages. In addition to the standards, effluent charges are levied on the BOD load discharged. The palm oil industry has made steady progress towards meeting the target of 100 mg/l BOD. A progressive reduction in the total BOD load discharged was recorded from 563 tons a day in 1978 to 5 tons in 1989 despite a 93 per cent increase in the number of palm oil mills over the same period.25 Differential Penalties In instances where monitoring by regulatory agencies is low, some non-compliance can be attributed to the optimizing behaviour of firms. This implies that firms may choose to remain non-compliant if the incremental cost of moving to compliance is greater than the expected loss associated with discovery and payment of penalties. Use of the Becker Model of Deterrence:26 The optimal penalty literature begins with Becker’s (1968) economic analysis of crime, the basic insight of which is that potential criminals respond to both the probability of detection and the severity of punishment if detected and convicted. Thus, deterrence may be enhanced either by raising the penalty, or by increasing monitoring activities to raise the likelihood that the offender will be caught. Since increasing the probability of detection requires some expenditure on government monitoring, Becker’s policy prescription is to set the probability of detection arbitrarily low, thus raising the penalty. 25 26 World Bank (1997), p. 42. Becker (1968). In reality, however, we do not observe such high penalties and low detection rates. Among the reasons for not imposing high sanctions are limited wealth of the offender, risk aversion, and exogenous conditions such as legislation or social norms of fairness. Thus, we are left with a government enforcement policy that requires a significant amount of monitoring expenditures. Several innovations have been suggested to reduce expensive government monitoring. One such innovation is the idea of differential penalties and differential approaches monitoring rates based on each firm’s prior compliance history. For example, SPCBs may employ differential norms for monitoring units based on complaints made or penalties issued in the past. Extending this idea further in the Indian context, one may consider the idea of differential consents. Consent terms may be rationalized by classifying industries depending on their polluting nature and consents may be issued on this basis for longer or shorter periods. This practice has apparently been introduced in Maharashtra where less polluting industries are issued consent for longer periods and potential heavy polluters are monitored more frequently by means of annual consents. Limited Use of Market Based Instruments (MBIs) Laws, systems, and approaches should be such that monitoring and active enforcement by regulatory agencies can reduce considerably in the long run. This can only happen if potential violators are provided with sufficient incentives to comply with the laws and penalties against non-compliance. Any incentive that does not equal the benefits gained through non-compliance27 will fail to achieve its purpose. At present, the government does provide some incentives, such as depreciation allowance, water cess, concessional custom duty, excise duty, soft loans for purchasing effluent control machinery, and targeted subsidies. However, there is little evidence of their effectiveness. Although they may appear to be blunter than other more targeted MBIs, the following approaches have proven easier to administer and implement. Removal of Subsidies: Many subsidies actually serve to reduce the cost of overexploiting or polluting the environment. Market based instruments that reduce subsidies that harm the environment reduce costs to the Treasury with important fiscal consequences. Recent estimates put environmentally damaging subsidies at over $240 billion per year in developing and transition economies.28 27 If incentives are not linked to actual levels of pollution in effluent, then firms could end up with getting incentives and not incurring the costs in abatement. 28 World Bank (1997), p. 10. Environment and Rehabilitation 103 For example, it has been argued that in Brazil, the exemption from taxation of virtually all agricultural income (allied to the fact that logging is regarded as proof of land occupancy) has provided strong perverse incentives to the private sector to acquire forestlands and to then deforest them.29 Self-Enforcing Policies: Recognizing that the highly ‘enforcement-intensive’ market based approaches of industrial countries are difficult to adopt, many developing countries are experimenting with more self-enforcing policies (such as deposit-refund schemes and performance bonds) with fewer points of intervention. In this manner, active enforcement is kept to a minimum while raising the financial costs of non-compliance. In both these cases, a financial bond or deposit is used to guarantee compliance with the desired outcome such as meeting environmental standards, or correctly disposing of waste products. The basic idea of a deposit-refund system is to let those who generate waste be responsible for the associated costs and to provide incentives to encourage waste recovery and recycling. For example, in 1989 Taiwan established a depositrefund system to recycle polyethylene terephthalate (PET), the plastic commonly used in soft drink bottles. Under the system, members of the industry have formed a foundation that administrates a joint recycling fund to cover costs of collection and recycling of the bottles. The fund is replenished from a deposit on the sale of each bottle. Those returning PET bottles to collection locations receive a refund per bottle. By 1992, the PET recycling rate was 80 per cent.30 Similarly, performance bonds require firms to post monetary bonds and forfeit them if they pollute. Taxes Environmental taxes send a signal of the right cost to polluters by including the lot of their negative externality costs. Rather than result in distortions, these taxes discourage ‘bads’ such as pollution. Taken a step further, environmental taxes can yield a ‘double dividend’ if the revenue from them is used to reduce and mitigate the effect of tax distortions. In situations where weak monitoring capabilities imposes constraints, blunter instruments, such as fuel taxes, with fewer points of intervention may be more appropriate. Reform of Water Cess: Though designed as a resource tax on specified water consuming units, the water cess is capable of serving as an effluent tax as well. It has been suggested that the cess be based on the effluent load generated by a firm so as to force industrial units to internalize the costs of their pollution.31 Another suggestion recommended is to levy the cess only on discharges in excess of the effluent standards. This is similar to China’s water pollution levy system given below. China’s Pollution Levy: An industrial pollution levy system exists in China on emissions that exceed standards. Government revenues from the pollution levy have increased rapidly, from 1.2 billion yuan in 1986 to 2.7 billion yuan in 1993. The pollution levy now provides about 15 per cent of all capital expenditure on pollution control and is the principal source of funding for regulatory enforcement activities!32 To provide incentives for enterprises to further reduce the (within-standard) pollutant discharges into water, a fee charged on the total quantity of wastewater discharged was introduced in 1993. The collections of this within-standard fee now amount to over 10 per cent of the collections of the over-standard fee. Results of the tests of the levy system suggest that the water pollution levy has been appropriately targeted and has been effective at reducing water pollution.33 Defining Property Rights Establishing property rights for land, water, and logging concessions provides a fundamental incentive for better resource management. When squatters become owners and forest dwellers have long-term user rights, there is a builtin incentive to exploit natural resources in a sustainable manner. Taking this argument further, property rights, say for clean air, can be negotiated with ‘polluters rights to pollute’. A fair trade-off can in principle be arrived upon through consultation between the directly affected stakeholders. Systems that debar or discourage such negotiation therefore end up being far from optimal. Establishing Tradable Permits Tradable pollution emission permits are the best known examples of market creation, and the evidence is that they are effective as long as a number of important design issues are addressed. First, the permit must actually create a property right. If there is any doubt on this count, then firms will not participate in the market. Second, the question of initial allocations of permits must be handled equitably. Finally, there must be no artificial obstructions to trading permits. The fact is that as institutional capacity is among the scarcest of resources in India, there would be good reason 31 29 30 Binswanger (1989). World Bank (1997), p. 36. 32 33 Gupta (1999), p. 112. World Bank (1997), p. 27. Afsah et al. (1996). 104 India Infrastructure Report 2002 to seek institutionally less-demanding approaches to pollution control as opposed to complicated tradable permit schemes. Keeping this in mind, one way to make a beginning could be to focus initially on only industrial estates to implement tradable permit schemes. This would facilitate identification of small groups of serious polluters, which the pollution control agency could regulate effectively with its existing resources. A suggestion is to cap the total emissions/discharges of the estate and have the potential occupiers carve up the available pollution limit among themselves. In the most recent amendments of both the Air and Water Acts, the public has been given right of access to certain information relating to consent conditions imposed by a Board (Section 49(2) of the Water Act and Section 43(2) of the Air Act) and a citizen can file a complaint with the court against any polluter after giving notice of 60 days to the prescribed authorities (Section 49(1)(b) of the Water Act and Section 43(1)(b) of the Air Act). This has not yet succeeded in facilitating the involvement of the public. Some suggestions to better facilitate public involvement follow. Participation and Community Involvement This may be useful especially when institutions are weak and enforcement expensive. Public participation and community involvement can be effective in enforcing sustainable resource use and adapting local conditions to development needs. This approach has been effectively utilized in the market economy, as evidenced by Japan. Local government and resident groups in Japan negotiate with firms to arrive at a detailed written agreement on emissions levels. Between 1971 and 1991, the number of agreements increased from approximately 2000 to 37,000.34 Example of Bhavani Dam:35 A similar approach was recommended when conflicts arose between agriculturalists, industry, and domestic users for water in the Bhavani River Basin in Tamil Nadu. Effluents discharged by industrial units upstream of the Bhavanisagar Dam would accumulate in the reservoir. This lead to farmers’ organizations and NGOs protesting against the effects of effluents on the quality of water for downstream uses such as irrigation and drinking, and to the seemingly unbelievable situation of the downstream users asking the authorities not to release the dam water. As redressal through the judicial system was thought to be an expensive and time-consuming process, the recommendations were that the stakeholders in the basin establish a forum whereby they could discuss and 34 35 Thomas and Belt (1997). Parikh, Parikh and Tata (1999), p. 6. negotiate the issues relating to the use of water resources. Informal and transparent contractual settlements could be worked out, and legal remedies were to be sought only if negotiated settlements failed. The functioning of the SPCBs as of now precludes participation of the local populace who may be directly affected by pollution of their environment. Community participation could take the form of community groups monitoring the samples generated by the polluting industries and getting the same tested (in private labs). Funding for such activity could be provided under the SPCB separately. This would effectively prevent the polluters–authorities nexus. The State Pollution Control Boards could also impart the necessary training to such groups. Public Discussion of the Environmental Assessment of Projects One avenue to participation that has proven to be particularly effective is the requirement for public discussion of environmental assessments of major projects. This has raised public awareness of environmental problems and given whole communities an effective voice in deciding how the development process will affect aspects of their environment. Attempt to Dilute Existing Legislation: In January 2001, the MoEF proposed to further amend the existing Environmental Impact Assessment Notification of 1994 (see Box 5.1.1). The main proposal is to drop the requirement to hold public hearings in the case of ‘Small Scale Industrial Units, Mining Projects up to twenty five hectares, widening and strengthening of Highways, and modernization of existing Irrigation Projects’, the argument being that ‘the environment impacts of such projects can be assessed on the basis of the information provided by the project proponents to the Ministry even without a public hearing’. This move has been widely denounced as an attempt to dilute the notification and reduce transparency. Small units cause at least as much as 40 per cent of the pollution in India, Mining units could be highly polluting and disrupt life for miles around. Role of NGOs NGOs can provide the vital link between industries, communities, and regulatory authorities. In a study conducted of a sample of 250 industrial plants in India, 51 plants indicated that they had undertaken abatement in response to NGO pressure and 102 said they had done so in response to complaints from neighbouring communities.36 In 1994, the Philippines received a $20.8 million grant from the Global Environmental Facility to conduct a seven-year project to conserve the nation’s biodiversity. Recognizing that the 36 Pargal et al. (1997), p. 6. Environment and Rehabilitation 105 Box 5.1.1 GBUS: Greens see Red over Project Clearance Norm Changes1 Shyam Parekh If a draft amendment to the Environment Protection Act comes through, almost 90 per cent of the industrial projects will come up without facing environmental public hearings (EPH). This, experts fear, will reverse years of conservation efforts. The draft notification was issued by the Union Ministry of Environment and Forests on 3 January, 2001. It proposes to amend the environment impact assessment (EIA) notification on ‘impact assessment of development projects (1994)’, issued under the Environment Protection Act (1986). ‘It is ironical that a mere three-line amendment will exclude small-scale industries, highway and mining projects besides modernization of existing irrigation projects from the hearings. Such projects comprise over 90 per cent of the total projects,’ says Mahesh Pandya of the Centre for Social Justice (CSJ), who attended a hearing in Delhi in this connection on 23 April. At present, as many as 30 types of projects are required to pass through the EPH to seek environmental clearance from the Centre. But with these changes four categories will be excluded. And small-scale industries are known for pollution. Instead of considering the pollution load and other factors, such industries will get clearance on the basis of the investment and area occupied. The Centre had imposed certain restrictions on expansion and modernization of any project, unless environmen t clearance was granted by the government. The draft notification states ‘It has been found that small-scale industrial units, mining projects with lease area up to 25 hectares, widening and strengthening of highways and modernization of existing irrigation projects have minimal impact, both on the environment and on people residing in the vicinity.’ It states that the environment impact of such projects can be assessed on the basis of the information provided by the project proponents to the ministry without a public hearing. However, Gujarat Pollution Control Board chairman K.V. Bhanujan says ‘such an amendment will not have any major impact on the environment’. Says Pandya, ‘There is a general tendency to set up industries even in the small-scale sector anywhere in a haphazard manner. This is more so in the case of Gujarat where many small-scale industries have mushroomed causing extensive damage to the environment. No systematic study is conducted or environmental status prepared, before setting up such units. Without proper effluent treatment plants such small-scale industries [SSIs] add to the pollution load if viewed collectively at the level of a large industrial unit.’ Some SSIs engaged in the manufacture of pesticides, radioactive goods, and hydrochloric acid figure in the category of highly polluting ventures. The pollution in the Golden Corridor between Vadodara and Vapi caused by small-scale industries is one such example. Experts believe that such units should not be excluded from the purview of rules relating to EPH as it is just because of the investment range that they are categorized as SSIs. The criteria for EPH should be based on the pollution load of the industry concerned irrespective of whether the investment involved is large or small. The CSJ represented that it is absolutely necessary to obtain environmental clearance through EPH in the case of highways passing through towns, cities and reserve forests. Such EPH should be held in all places through which the highway passes. Besides, mining projects related to fluospar and radioactive minerals cause undue damage to environment. Such industries should not be exempted from the EPH on the basis of the limited lease area of occupation. 1 This piece is reproduced by arrangement with the Times of India, and is the copyright of Bennet, Coleman & Co. Ltd. Source: 18 May 2001, Times of India. national government alone would not be able to protect biodiversity, the project was designed to form partnerships between the public and private sectors by integrating the assistance of NGOs into the management of protected areas at national and local levels. This arrangement is being implemented at 10 priority protected areas (a total of 1.25 million hectares of land, wetland, and water areas).37 accountable. Such public disclosure and public education campaigns often have a much more powerful impact than more traditional regulatory approaches. In addition, these offer the possibility of fulfilling the large and growing need for pollution control despite limited budgets and staffs, by allowing the public to monitor the performance of individual firms and their compliance with environmental regulation. Information Disclosure Example of Indonesia—PROPER: Faced with acute pollution problems, shortage of environmental protection funding, and weak enforcement of regulations, the Indonesian government has experimented with a programme for rating and publicly disclosing the environmental Informed public opinion can also play a powerful role in exposing and holding private firms and government agencies 37 World Bank (1997), p. 49. 106 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 5.1.2 The Politics of Pollution1 Delhi Janwadi Adhikar Manch It is nobody’s argument that pollution is not a serious problem. It affects us all, and in particular the poor. The poor with their wretched living and working conditions, negligible access to health care, and lack of any alternatives have to bear the brunt of the ill effects of pollution. A rational approach to tackling the problems of pollution ought bear in mind the causes, the interlinkages between the various causes, and the different sections of society affected by uneven effects of the same. We have outlined below the major causes of pollution in the city of Delhi, the sections responsible for this pollution, and those chiefly affected by it. In the context we have attempted to show the total irrationality of the approaches of various governments, the judiciary, and the administration to solving the problems of pollution. A major source of air pollution is the vehicles that ply in the city, contributing 64 per cent of Delhi’s air pollution. Pollutants from vehicles are no less dangerous than industrial pollutants. Despite the welcome introduction of compressed natural gas (CNG), most vehicles in Delhi burn up diesel or petrol. The total number of vehicles in Delhi shot up from 16 lakh in 1990 to 26 lakh by 1996, and is projected to reach 46 lakh vehicles this year! Given that private cars and two-wheelers account for the majority of the 46 lakh vehicles, it is clear that the problem of air pollution cannot be tackled without curbing this unrestricted growth of private transport. This is not possible without providing a vibrant and viable public transport system. It allowed public transport in Delhi to degenerate. Another major cause of pollution in Delhi is its industry. Some sources put the number of polluting units in Delhi at around 7000 but even official figures vary. The Central government’s White Paper on Pollution in Delhi (1997) states that the volume of air pollutants that Delhi has to breathe each day increased from 1450 tons per day in 1991 to 2890 tons by 1995. Obviously, it has increased since then. Industry used to contribute about 12 per cent of air pollution in Delhi, or about 325 to 350 tons each day. But with the closure of 243 brick kilns and 46 hot mix plants in 1996, the contribution of industry has reduced to less than 10 per cent. However, given the toxicity of the fumes emitted, the effects of these pollutants are far more significant than the mere volume. For instance, among the list of 27 industries targeted by the Delhi government are electroplating, anodizing, plastic, PVC compounds, and other industries, all of which emit highly toxic fumes during the production process. The Yamuna river is the main natural source of water to the city. At the point at which the river leaves Delhi at Okhla, the level of oxygen in the water has been measured at 1.3 mg/litre against the minimum permissible level of 5 mg/litre, and the total coliforms (bacteria) at 329,312 per 100 ml against the acceptable level of 500 per 100 ml. Contrast this with the levels when the water enters Delhi at Wazirabad: the dissolved oxygen level is 7.5 mg/litre, and the bacterial level 8506 per 100 ml. The total wastewater discharged in Delhi is about 2160 million litres a day (mld). Of this, industrial pollution contributes 320 mld; much of the rest derives from domestic sewage. Again, the contribution to toxicity of industrial pollutants is more than as suggested by the volume of pollutants, given the use and unregulated disposal of chemicals and toxic substances. These either seep into the ground to contaminate groundwater or flow into the Yamuna via twenty drains in the city, of which the Najafgarh drain alone contributes over 40 per cent. There is another factor that makes the problem of industrial water pollution more acute. At Wazirabad Barrage, the point where the river enters Delhi from the north, the water is trapped to supply Delhi its drinking water. During the dry season, none of this water is allowed to enter Delhi. Hence from October to June, the ‘water’ that flows through Delhi is the untreated or partially treated sewage and industrial waste that flows into the Yamuna through the drains, besides some irrigation water for the Agra canal. This has ominous consequences for those who use the river water downstream. WHO ARE THE MOST AFFECTED? The effects of pollution on an individual’s health are also influenced by incomes because high incomes improve the ability to mitigate its worst effects. Better nutrition, airconditioning and bottle water are some means by which people can partially combat pollution. Yet there is no denying that these effects are nearly universal. For instance, a high proportion of children in Delhi below the age of 5 years suffer from respiratory disorders, and this affects children from most income groups. But, even here the impact on the poor is more, given their general poorer health, worse living conditions, and limited access to health care. The sections most affected by industrial pollution are the workers themselves. Most units that have been targeted for closure in Delhi operate in small spaces of around 50 square metres, with little or no ventilation. In Wazirpur, acid is used in the process of steel production. The fumes are so strong that the workers regularly find it difficult to breathe. For instance, workers in a copper wire unit in Vishwas Nagar knew fully well that they are more affected by the pollutants than those outside. In this factory, copper is cleaned with chemicals, which emit fumes. Then varnish is applied to the copper wire, and it is heated to help it dry quickly. This emits a vapour, the regular inhalation of which causes TB. Those we spoke to said they eat gur regularly to prevent getting TB, and knew several other workers suffering from TB. Among the list of 27 industries targeted by the government initially is PVC (poly-vinyl chloride), of which hundreds of small units have shut down in Vishwas Nagar in East Delhi. PVC, or poly-vinyl chloride, is one the most widely used types of plastic. 1 This paper draws much from DJAM (2001a) and DJAM (2001b). Environment and Rehabilitation 107 In the manufacture of PVC pellets, dioxins are emitted, among which are some that cause cancer as observed by the WHO in 1997. Besides, in order to give PVC flexibility and strength, a plasticzer called dibutyle phthalate is used in its manufacturing process. As a recent report states, phthalates can harm the reproductive system, and can cause cancer of the liver and the kidneys. Phthalates ‘are found in the atmosphere of primary PVC processing plants. This results in significant exposure to workers’. A study concluded that the greatest potential for exposure to dibutyl phthalate is to individuals who manufacture or handle these substances (http:// 198.252.9.108/govper/EnvHealthPer/2000/Octoo.pdf (Human Expose Estimates for pthalates). Workers know that the pollution caused within a factory affects them, but as one worker in Tri Nagar said, ‘Hum kya kar sakte hain? Naukri karna hai’. They have no option. A majority of them are not unionized. The struggles of workers in this city as elsewhere have mostly remained confined to wage and economic demands. Issues of workers’ safety, health, and working conditions do not find a place in these struggles. Besides those working inside dingy, closed units, those most immediately affected are their families who live in jhuggi–jhopris in the vicinity of industrial areas. It is they who are most exposed to the toxic fumes, chemicals, and drink the groundwater that is contaminated by toxic pollutants. In Wazirpur, which is a centre of steel pickling and electroplating industry, acid and chemicals used in steel processing collect in little lethal puddles on the road, through which the jhuggis’ residents walk all the time. The air is foul with the smell of acid. During monsoon, the drains overflow, forcing people to walk through acid-laden water. Over years of industrial activity, the acid has seeped into the ground and contaminated the water supply. Besides contaminated water, the solid waste generated from processing steel lies around in piles. Studies have shown that they contain toxic heavy metals such as chromium, nickel, lead, and cadmium, which seep into the groundwater. This has serious long-term effects on the slum dwellers. A third section of people affected by the polluted river are those who use the water downstream. The Central Pollution Control Board report says that the ‘500 km stretch from Delhi to Chambal [via Mathura, Agra, and Etawah] does not meet the criteria for its designated use, even in the monsoon season’. Pesticides such as DDT, BHC (benzene hexa chloride), and heavy metals are found in the water. It is the poor who use this heavily contaminated water for bathing. In contrast to these poorest sections of people who are most affected by pollution, it is the elite that is most responsible for it. None of the 46 lakh vehicles that blacken the air we breathe are owned by workers from Vishwas Nagar, Tri Nagar, or Okhla whose livelihood has been hit. Contrary to middle class perception, the sewage that flows into the Yamuna is not caused by workers’ families in jhuggis: two-thirds of Delhi’s population receives little over two buckets per person per day. Residents of Golf Links, Sundar Nagar, Vasant Vihar, and other elite colonies use over 450 litres or thirty buckets per person daily. Despite being the root cause of much of the pollution, elites are disproportionately less affected by it. Middle and upper classes have access to better nutrition and can withstand infection better. They are cushioned from the effects of pollution in more direct ways. It is they who have the resources to instal Aquaguard and other systems that purify drinking water. Today, there are numerous domestic and international companies that sell bottled water, at a price that only the rich can afford, enabling these companies to make huge profits from the failure of governments to provide clean water to those who can buy it. The state’s response has been to close or shift out industries, whatever the human costs of such actions have been. Relocating industry will only export pollution to neighbouring areas. Closure is a knee-jerk reaction, which affects those who are already most affected by pollution. Any resolution of the current situation must adopt a holistic perspective, taking into account those who work in the factories, and their families who live in the area, their physical safety, health, and well-being. And for those same reasons, if small industry is to continue in Delhi, it cannot continue under the conditions that operate at the moment, violating most labour laws, safety norms, and in abysmal working conditions. performance of Indonesian factories. The aim of the programme is to have a low-cost but effective means of putting public pressure on factories and providing incentives for factories to adopt cleaner technologies. The government, the community, and the market apply the pressure, through public disclosure, on factories with poor environmental performance. The Program for Pollution Control, Evaluation and Rating (PROPER) was introduced to the Indonesian public in June 1995. Based on the government’s evaluation of its environmental performance, a plant is assigned a rating by PROPER. In the pilot phase of PROPER, 187 plants were rated. Those that rated poorly were privately notified and given time until December 1995 to improve. Preliminary results show that PROPER has a positive impact on factories’ environmental performance. By December 1995—the time of full disclosure—the number of poorly rated plants had reduced.38 Environmental Audits and Self-Monitoring by Industry: Experience in industrialized countries has also shown that firms react to popular pressure. To generate such pressure, citizens may be empowered through a ‘right to information’. Making publicly available emission measurements and audit of firms can help citizens to be vigilant. In the Indian context, publishing details of consent applications, reasons for rejection and so forth would be the starting point. Self-reporting is a substitute for government monitoring efforts that may reduce enforcement costs without 38 World Bank (1997), p. 46. 108 India Infrastructure Report 2002 compromising deterrence. Polluters are told to report any violation of pollution standards. The magnitude of penalty they receive will depend on whether the violation is reported voluntarily or if government enforcement authorities discover it when no self-report has been made. If it is the latter, then the penalty may be considerably higher. Community Pressure It has become increasingly evident that it is virtually impossible for the government to monitor the activities of individuals, industries, and institutions across the country. If the government is the sole monitoring agency, then corruption and inefficiency are likely to creep into the system. Vigilant stakeholders, with strong and technically equipped institutional support, can play a very important role in managing the environment. ‘Coasean Bargaining’: The starting point for thinking about community bargaining approaches to pollution control is the Coase Theorem. In his landmark essay, Ronald Coase (1960) pointed out that pollution control situations have a certain symmetry. Inefficient pollution imposes costs on victims, which exceed the costs of controlling that pollution. In other words, the marginal benefits of pollution control exceed the marginal costs. The existence of inefficient pollution damage therefore provides a motivation for the victims to take corrective action, even in the absence of any such incentives by the polluters. Such corrective action in the form of informal regulation will be likely wherever formal regulation leaves a gap between actual and locally preferred environmental quality. Informal regulation can take many forms, including demands for compensation by community groups; social ostracism of the firm’s employees; the threat of physical violence; boycotting the firm’s products; and monitoring and publicizing the firm’s emissions. Implicitly, such actions force recognition of the community’s property rights in the local environment. They frequently work because firms do not operate in a social vacuum. Direct Negotiation: This works on the premise that when formal regulatory mechanisms are absent or ineffective, communities will seek other means of translating their preferences into reality. Many cases of direct negotiation between plant managements and local inhabitants have been documented around the world. These informal arrangements may rely upon reputation concerns, direct threats, or social pressure (as seen in the Bhavani Dam example given above). Recent empirical work has indicated the widespread existence of such ‘informal regulation’. Communities are often able to negotiate with or otherwise informally pressure polluting plants in their vicinity to clean up.39 Engaging All Stakeholders: In light of the above, one of the implications for environmental regulatory policy is that the regulators no longer need to think of themselves as the sole enforcers. When participation by the community is introduced into the framework, supplemented by selective MBIs, then monitoring and enforcing rules and standards are no longer solely confined to the regulator. Environmental governance stands would improve greatly working through very important leverage points of charge, viz. in empowered communities, and the market. 5.2 THE ASSAULT ON WORKERS IN LAND USE POLICY AND PRACTICE IN DELHI40 Delhi Janwadi Adhikar Manch41 In the last decade, the working class of Delhi has come under relentless attack. Hitherto, they were victims of a lowwage economy with little urban space that had compelled them into living and working in sub-human conditions. Now as industries close they are threatened by the spectre of joblessness and loss of their shelter, and are therefore forced to quit Delhi. 39 Pargal et al. (1996), p. 1. 40 This paper draws much from DJAM (2001a), and DJAM (2001b). 41 Delhi Janwadi Manch is an NGO based in Delhi working for the rights of workers and the poor displaced by industrial relocation. It was formed on 16 December 1996, when various organizations came together to address issues arising from a series of Supreme The link between livelihood, shelter, and the right to life was clearly elucidated in the Olga Tellis case in 1986. The sweep of the right to life, conferred by Article 21 is wide and far-reaching. ‘Life’ means something more than mere animal existence. . . . An . . . important facet of that right is the right to livelihood, because no person can live without Court orders relocating polluting industries and cleaning up Delhi. Since then the DJAM has been organizing protest dharnas, holding public meetings, campaigning against the Supreme Court order through pamphlets, cultural programmes and rallies, mobilizing opinion in universities, the media and the public at large, joining the struggle of jhuggi dwellers against the ongoing demolition drive. Environment and Rehabilitation 109 the means of living, that is, the means of livelihood. If the right to livelihood is not treated as a part of the constitutional right to life, the easiest way of depriving a person of his right to life would be to deprive him of his means of livelihood to the point of abrogation. [Supreme Court of India, from the Olga Tellis case (AIR 1986 SC 180)] Today, fifteen years later, the milieu has changed and the right to life is being threatened by the same Court in the name of fighting pollution. There is no doubt that pollution is a major impediment to the well being of people at large, particularly for those who are compelled to work in hellholes and reside in crowded colonies or jhuggi-jhopris, which are poor in terms of civic amenities. Urban pollution also tends to pollute adjoining areas. It is our contention that if the aim is to fight pollution and improve the health of the citizens then it should begin by addressing the issue in terms of the disproportionately high impact of pollution on the lives of the poor working class. If the Supreme Court itself violates the right to life of citizens and displaces lakhs of the working class, then the message is loud and clear that the issue of survival of the workers has become non-justiciable. This section brings out the massive displacement of ordinary people with the closure of industries and the demolition of slums, the working and living conditions of the bulk of Delhi’s citizens, and the politics of slum clearance and pollution. THE LEGAL CONTEXT In 1985, a lawyer M.C. Mehta filed a writ in the Supreme Court, No. 4677/85, on pollution of the Ganga river. Since 1996, the Supreme Court began issuing a series of orders pertaining to the closure or relocation of industries from Delhi. In 1996, it ordered that: 168 ‘hazardous and noxious’ and ‘heavy and large’ industries be moved from Delhi by 30 November 1996; 513 ‘extensive’ industries (employing between 50 and 500 workers) in residential areas and 334 such units in other ‘non-conforming’ areas be relocated or closed down by 31 January 1997; 46 hot-mix plants be closed down by 28 February 1997; and 243 brick kilns be closed by 30 June 1997. Around 50,000 workers lost their jobs following these Supreme Court orders. In February 1996, in another writ petition, filed in 1994, pertaining to pollution of the Yamuna river, the Court directed the Delhi government to undertake the construction of 15 Common Effluent Treatment Plants (CETPs) to treat industrial water pollution emanating from Delhi’s 28 designated industrial areas. The Delhi and central governments were to pay a combined 50 per cent of the cost and the remaining half was to come from contributions by industry. Not a single industrial association has paid up its 50 per cent till date. Little progress having taken place for over five years, on 13 September 1999, the Court asked the Delhi government to ensure that, from 1 November 1999, no industrial effluent is allowed to be discharged directly or indirectly into the Yamuna. The second round of closures, this time only of polluting units, began in January 2000, continuing intensively until March. Hundreds of polluting units were closed down by teams of SDMs (Subjudicial magistrates). They had a rough list of polluting units provided by the Delhi Pollution Control Committee (DPCC)—based on a survey that DPCC officials themselves confess as being unscientifically prepared — and also identified other polluting units during their visits and sealed them with police assistance. According to an affidavit filed on 8 July by the Chief Secretary, Delhi government, as many as 3177 units had been shut down by early July 2000. The further sealing of 27 types of polluting industries, in non-conforming areas, began in late November 2000 (see Box 5.2.1). The Court order made it clear that this was an interim step and that the rest of the units operating in violation of the Master Plan, were to be closed or relocated at a later date. On 25 January 2001, it decreed that all ‘potentially polluting units would be targeted. The closure process is thus scarcely complete. At the time of writing this report, a further 33 types of industrial units within the ‘F’ category of the Master Plan were being sealed. Whether they are all actually polluting is unclear. The Court had asked the government how many polluting units there were in Delhi. In its stead, the government said its survey of 1996 had revealed that there were 38,936 units under the ‘F’ category, more than 32,000 of which were in non-conforming areas. In the face of opposition from industry, the government has now been saying that they are not all polluting. Whatever the real picture may be, closures are carrying on relentlessly day after day. In addition, there are thousands of units beyond a certain size that operate in non-conforming areas. A high-powered committee made a classification of industry as per the Master Plan, and proposed the closure of industries operating in non-conforming and residential areas. Following which, in 1997, the Court ordered units in residential areas to close down. Their reported numbers vary greatly. In the hearing on 24 January earlier this year, it was said that a further 57,000 industrial units could close down. Pressurized by the factory owners, the government has been pleading during the past few hearings that residential areas where industry currently occupies over 70 per cent of the area be categorized as ‘industrial’. At the same time, it has invited applications from industry to relocate outside Delhi. Hence, besides these widespread closures, there has been a process of relocation that has been inching forward over the last four years or so. Over 52,000 applications for relocation were 110 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 5.2.1 Industrial Closures in Delhi Following a Supreme Court order (of 12 September 2000) that directed the Delhi government that ‘all polluting industries of whatever category operating in residential areas must be asked to shut down’, teams of sub-divisional magistrates accompanied by police personnel had begun sealing hundreds of ‘non-conforming’ polluting units. Twenty-seven ‘undisputedly polluting industries’— acids and chemicals, dyeing and bleaching, electroplating, glass products, plastic dye, polythene, steel re-rolling, PVC compounds, among others—listed in Annexure III ‘F’ in the Master Plan of Delhi (MPD 2001) were initially targeted by the government. Over the next few weeks, hundreds of factories in Tri Nagar, Keshopuram, Vishwas Nagar, Rohini, Narela, Samaipur Badli, and numerous other areas were sealed. The official count of industries sealed in this round of closure between November to January 2001 is 2856. In a matter of a few weeks, according to our estimate, over 4000 industrial units in this city ceased functioning, throwing over 50,000 workers out of work. When teams from the Delhi Janwadi Adhikar Manch (DJAM) surveyed some of these localities in December, all kinds of economic activity were in the process of winding down. The effects of industrial closure tend to be widespread, having negative spin-off effects in the locality in general, beyond the factory. All kinds of small establishments and the casual, contract, or the informal workforce within them had been hit by closures. The majority of these migrant workers from villages and small towns in U.P., Bihar, and other states are completely at a loss. When the current round of closures first began in late November last year, thousands of workers took to the streets. It was a scene Delhi has rarely witnessed. Factory owners who needed the workers to add to their protest against closures facilitated these initial protests. Three workers were killed in police firing in Vishwas Nagar on 20 November, but not a rupee’s compensation was forthcoming from a single factory owner. Workers and shopkeepers of the area had collected money to send to the families of the dead. Around sixty workers languished in Tihar Jail, as no factory owner wanted to bail them out. There was intense anger against factory owners and particularly against the Delhi government. Those affected comprise a completely non-unionized workforce given the nature of units and production processes in these areas. In the kind of industrial and ancillary services units that exist in Delhi, there is no security of job. Workers who have worked in a factory for years can be abruptly thrown out of a job. In some cases, they were asked to come back after 3 January (on the day of the next hearing of the case in the Supreme Court) by which time, they were told, the situation would be clearer. Some were told that the factory would reopen on that date. Most were simply asked to leave, or return to their villages. In some cases, workers were physically forced to sign settlement papers by factory owners with the use of goons and by bribing the local police. The workers received just the month’s wages due to them. Some received nothing at all since they had taken advances against their wages. Few have found alternative, even if low paying, jobs in the city. Most workers have returned to their villages, unable to pay the rents for jhuggis in the city. Even, four months after the closures began, those who left in the hope of being called back to work had not still returned to the city. Most workers in fact hail from families that do have small amounts of land, but which is not enough to support the numbers that are dependent upon it. Hence, those affected by these ongoing closures includes not just the thousands of workers in the city, but lakhs of people in the villages and small towns depending on regular money orders from Delhi. submitted, of which 22,000 units have been approved and deposits paid. The White Paper on ‘Pollution in Delhi with an Action Plan’ (1997) brought out by the Ministry of Environment and Forests, Government of India describes the problem as being the ‘rise in population and growth in economic activity [which] has led to increase in pollution in Delhi’. Its last chapter affirms that ‘the Action Plan goes beyond just controlling pollution’. It also emphasizes ‘planning and development of infrastructure which will mitigate pollution’. Towards this end, the objective was to ‘contain the pressure of population on Delhi. The [Action] Plan envisages the deflection of a population of 20 lakhs from Delhi. Accordingly, the development of priority [satellite] towns and complexes in the NCR outside Delhi has been projected’. Such efforts had in the past proven counterproductive. For instance, the Master Plan had sought to develop Meerut, Rewari, Khurja, Rohtak, and Panipat so as to decentralize and decongest Delhi. Not only has Delhi continued to grow and expand, these towns themselves suffer from excessive air, water, and noise pollution. In other words, shifting polluting industries to satellite towns is not a solution but a problem. But as we discuss later in this report, pollution appears to be an excuse being used to throw workers and their families out of the city (see Box 5.2.2). The Second Master Plan for Delhi (MPD 2001) recommended that hazardous and noxious industries [Annexure H (a)] not be permitted in Delhi. Similarly, heavy and large industries [category H (b)] would have to be shifted outside Delhi to the National Capital Region (NCR). These are the categories and industries that the Supreme Court targeted in its order of 8 July 1996, leading to the closure in 1996 and 1997 of 168 hazardous industrial units, 243 brick kilns, and 46 hotmix plants. Environment and Rehabilitation 111 The Master Plan also refers to ‘extensive industries’, which include 81 types of industries, currently the subject of government attention. Among the closures in 1996 were 847 extensive units in residential and non-conforming areas. According to the Master Plan, new extensive units were to be permitted only in identified extensive industrial areas, of which there are only eight locations: Chilla, Okhla, Najafgarh Road, Mayapuri, Rohtak Road, Patparganj, South of Jahangirpuri, Mother Diary, and Samaipur Badli. More crucially, extensive units in non-conforming areas had to shift to these specified areas or presumably shut down. It is not clear how these already crowded industrial areas could accommodate these non-conforming units. Further, light and service industries in non-conforming areas—of which there are thousands—would have to shift to their industrial use zones: those with 20 or more workers within 3 years; those with fewer workers would be reviewed after five or ten years, hence giving them time for relocation. Then, no new industrial unit of any kind employing more than fifty workers would be permitted in Delhi. Finally, only ‘household’ industrial units with a maximum of five workers and one kilowatt power would be allowed in residential areas, but no polluting unit would be allowed as household industry. This, in essence, is a restructuring of the manufacturing character of the city, for a city of this size would always have small ‘household’ industry operating, legally or illegally. Anything larger than that in commercial, residential, or other non-conforming areas are scheduled to be evicted (for more on eviction see Box 5.2.3). The Master Plan refers to 16 new industrial areas for the growing number of light and service industries, but only eight have been developed. Besides, two areas for extensive industries had been promised but none was developed. Of the 58 modifications to the Master Plan from 1990 to 1998 pertaining to 5007 hectares, land use was modified to ‘manufacturing’ only in four cases, totalling merely 38 hectares. Over the same period, land redesignated as ‘residential areas’ totalled 2782 hectares, and nearly 200 hectares was changed to ‘commercial’ purposes. By lending its institutional legitimacy to this restructuring agenda, the Supreme Court has played a role that is nothing short of dubious. The Court’s periodic obiter dicta regarding closure and the accompanying demolition of jhuggi–jhopris betrays its class character. It has referred to the protests of workers against closures in late November as ‘hooliganism’ having taken over the city. More important than employment, the Court said, was the health of the city residents, a blinkered perspective of health that excludes the well being of those who make the city what it is in the first place. This concern for quality of life places a disproportionate responsibility on those who sell their labour power in order to secure a life. As one woman in a jhuggi in East Delhi angrily told us, ‘We have lived here for twenty years. Delhi was made by our labour, and now they are throwing us out.’ The apex Court believes that migrants, who form the bulk of the city’s workforce, will have no objection to moving 40–50 kilometres away. There is, however, absolutely no guarantee at all that there will be a job calling them there. The silence of the Court on the matter of livelihood of the working class is shocking given that it cannot be unaware of the huge social consequences of the closures of 1996, when thousands of workers were abruptly thrown out of their jobs. In 1996, the Court had at least mentioned some compensation for workers. Expectedly, the actual task of their payment was undertaken only when workers began to agitate for compensation, and even turned to the courts. Yet, the majority of them did not receive anything, because the majority was employed in units where workers were not unionized. Even in large, unionized workplaces—such as Shriram Foods and Fertilisers, with its workforce of over 1350—the Court finally dismissed the case of the contract workers. As a result more than 50,000 workers were reduced to destitution. Workers and slum dwellers of Delhi as we can see continue to live under a perpetual state of an undeclared ‘Emergency’ that today derives legitimacy from an active judiciary. On 16 February 2000 in the public interest litigation (PIL) of Almitra Patel, etc., the Court ordered the Delhi government and other authorities to remove slums and unauthorized colonies from the public land threatening to dispossess an estimated 35 lakh people. The Court stated that, ‘The promise of free land at the tax payers cost, in place of a jhuggi is a proposal which attracts many land grabbers. Rewarding an encroacher on public land with a free alternate site is like giving a reward to a pickpocket’. Further, ‘When a large number of inhabitants live in unauthorised colonies, with no proper means of dealing with domestic effluents, or in slums with no care for hygiene, the problem becomes more complex.’ The underlying assumptions link survival needs with the pernicious activity of the land mafia and dismiss the dire need for housing of working people by punishing them for being unable to afford clean living space! It amounts to victimizing the victim, inverting all notions of justice and fairness. Not a word about whether the authorities are obliged to rehabilitate them or not. Equally, there was no concern expressed over lack of sewage, latrines, drinking water, and electricity for the 35 lakhs who reside in slums. Delhi has around 1100 bastis comprising six lakh jhuggis spread over 9.5 sq kms. Most slums are located on land owned by DDA, MCD, NDMC, and the railways, concentrated mainly around industrial areas. The problem of shortage of dwellings, that too affordable dwelling, has resulted in the proliferation of slums. This is 112 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 5.2.2 Restructuring the City Having for years allowed industrial units to thrive in residential and other areas, it needs to be asked why the government and the Court have suddenly woken up at this time to the existence of industries deemed to be ‘non-conforming’ as per the Master Plan. As it is, Delhi’s industrial growth, post-1947, has always run contrary to conforming, regulated industrial development envisaged in the Master Plan. By 2000, the Delhi government declared there were 121,000 industrial units that did not ‘conform’ as per the Master Plan. Durng 1980s and 1990s around 4500—5000 new industrial units were added to the city each year, most of them in non-conforming areas, operating with a proxy licence that they renew each year. Currently, besides the 28 designated industrial areas, there are 37 other ‘non-conforming’ areas in which industry thrives. In fifteen of these non-conforming areas, industry has grown to such a degree that over 70 per cent of it has been taken over by industrial activity. This proliferation of industry has partly been encouraged by the traditional support of the government to the small scale sector. Another significant factor of this proliferation is the decentralized process of capitalist production. Enforcing the Master Plan’s provisions described below and limiting industry by administrative and judicial interventions runs counter to this production system. Hence, shifting industrial units elsewhere does not mean that conditions will evolve into something better. Many will just close down while others will come up in other areas under the same working and operating conditions. The real agenda may not be to control pollution, but to shift it elsewhere. These actions are directed at altering the manufacturing aspects of the city, to administratively facilitate the removing of manufacturing processes from the city to the degree possible, and transform the city to a centre of service industries. If one were to view what has happened in Delhi since, a similar pattern emerges. At least 50,000 workers lost their jobs following the closures of over one thousand industrial units in late 1996–7. In early 2000, hundreds of industrial units were shut down following the Supreme Court orders that industries be forbidden from polluting the Yamuna. And in the ongoing round of closures that began in November last year, the authorities have already sealed thousands of units. Many other units had already stopped operating before official teams visited them. According to an official figure, in the hearings on 24 January, the government said that from November to January 2001, 19,496 units had been scrutinized and 2856 units closed, in 1373 units there was no industrial activity, and in 1549 there was change of trade. By any estimate, at least a lakh or more manufacturing jobs have disappeared from this city in less than five years! A panic has been created about the entry of ‘outsiders’ into Delhi who are threatening to change the very profile of the city. Their ‘illegal entry’ has allegedly not only depleted the water and electricity but has also created a law and order problem. It is claimed that only by cleansing Delhi of these hordes of migrant ‘outsiders’ can normalcy be restored. ‘Outsiders’ are not the well-to-do white collar executives and corporate but only the working class people hailing from U.P. and Bihar to Orissa and Tamil Nadu who live in sub-human conditions and contribute their hard labour to the building of this city, its upkeep and provide various services. Urbanization necessarily means the movement of workers and others to cities, and there is nothing dysfunctional about it. But high income inequalities, joblessness, slow growth of manufacturing, and even when there is some growth in manufacturing, its poor employment elasticities result in enhanced migration to the cities. Land reforms could have considerably stemmed this outflow from rural areas. The same State that is today throwing out lakhs of workers and the poor from Delhi was responsible for bringing them here in the first place. The setting up of flyovers, stadiums, and hotels for the Asian Games in 1982 brought in two lakh workers to Delhi. A large section of them remained here as they got engaged in other production processes. They worked in small-scale industries. The ‘smooth’ flyovers, and ‘beautiful’ south and central Delhi, and the country clubs, upmarket restaurants and shopping arcades have been built by the very same ‘dirty’ workers. The vast majority of migrants who come to Delhi are compelled to live in jhuggies under the most adverse circumstances. Whether it is water, electricity, toilets, or ration, they struggle for each little thing and live in the perpetual uncertainty of losing the little world they have made for themselves. Delhi has a population of over 1.4 crore and of this an estimated 30 lakhs live in 1073 unauthorized colonies. Around 35 lakh people inhabit 6 lakh jhuggies spread over 1100 bastis while there are yet another 20 lakhs in the resettlement colonies. In effect, over 60 per cent of Delhi’s population live in areas where there is a lack of basic requirements like proper water supply, drains, toilets, health facilities, or schooling for children. They are constantly prone not only to the vagaries of nature but also most vulnerable to epidemics and diseases. Today the assault on them has mounted. Evictions have became the order of the day. a reflection of the main problem of an absence of equitable land distribution. In virtually all metropolis in India, nearly two-thirds of the population is forced to live in one-tenth of the urban land. In Delhi, just 1.5 per cent of the total urban land is under slums! For more than 35 lakh slum dwellers in Delhi, losing their slums would amount to losing their means to earn a living. This was clearly elucidated in the famous Olga Tellis case decided by the Supreme Court in 1986. The apex Court had then stated that the eviction of pavement dwellers will lead to deprivation of their livelihood and consequently to the deprivation of life guaranteed to every person under Article 21 of the Constitution. This can be guaranteed and ensured by the government if there is adequate supply of Environment and Rehabilitation 113 Box 5.2.3 Evictions During the period of Emergency (1975–7), almost seven lakh slum dwellers were evicted to the fringes of the city of Delhi under the direct orders of Jagmohan, who was the Chairman of the Delhi Development Authority (DDA) at the time. Ever since then, there has been a relentless spate of slum demolitions without giving any notice or compensation to the people. The passing of the Anti-Encroachment Bill in May 1984 in Parliament made the very fact of residing in a basti an illegal act! This strengthened the hands of political parties and the land mafia who work hand in glove at exacting votes, bribes, and obeisance from thousands who live in constant anxiety of losing their housing. The courts in their eviction orders have cited pollution, beautification of Delhi, or the ‘illegal’ occupation of land as the reasons. Six hundred families who were victims of the 1984 Sikh massacres in Delhi, and were yet to receive alternate housing, were evicted again in 1996 from their jhuggies in Tilak Vihar. Entire families sat in protest for months on end at Jantar Mantar to draw the attention of the government to their plight. But they had to give up, when the government decided that Jantar Mantar would no longer be a site of protest in Delhi. On 13 November 1996, the BSF (Border Security Force) evicted 160 families living in the old stables of Pataudi House ever since 1947. Free transport was provided and their departure was recorded on video cameras to record the help rendered by the government while evicting! Tughlaqabad is the last station of the Northern Railways on the track leading to Faridabad. All bastis lying on both sides of the track from New Delhi railway station to Tughlaqabad have either been destroyed or are facing the threat of demolition any day. The predominantly Dalit community of both Thompson Basti and Kasturba Camp were evicted by force for occupying land belonging to the Railways. One hundred and twenty-five out of the 600 jhuggies in Thompson Basti near the New Delhi railway station were earmarked for demolition. On 7 July 1997, the bulldozer razed it to the ground, but Thompson Press is yet to build its beautiful park for which the basti was removed! Both police and the RPF (Railway Protection Force) directed sexual abuse at the resisting women. Some of the residents had returned with a reassurance just 24 hours earlier from the then Prime Minister I.K. Gujral, that the demolition would not take place! In June 1997, in Kasturba Camp, located on Railway land near the Tughlaqabad station, when the bulldozer was unable to demolish the 1500 jhuggies and the people fought back the demolition squad, the entire area was set ablaze to rid the land of jhuggies. In the process, the adjoining jhuggies on DDA land were also burnt down. People were barely able to retrieve their few belongings. Around the same time, Harkesh Nagar, also located on Railway land on Mathura Road, was similarly demolished. But the slum dwellers of Anna Nagar and VP Singh camp continue to resist demolition. The residents of VP Singh camp near Tughlaqabad, living on the land of both the railways and CONCOR India (Container Corporation of India), are engaged in a legal battle. The 10,000 residents of Anna Nagar located on the same Northern Railway track near the ITO [Income Tax Office] are fighting a legal battle for their jhuggies that the Railways is bent upon taking over. In 1996, 300 jhuggies of Naya Bazaar in Peeli Kothi in Old Delhi were destroyed with the assistance of police and no alternate housing was provided. In the case of both Rampuri near Janakpuri and Indira camp in Jhilmil, communal tensions were whipped up amongst the slum dwellers to distract them from the immediate demolitions that took place without any prior notice. Resistance against forcible evictions continues unabated. The residents of VP Singh camp had blockaded the roads leading to the jhuggies in July 1997 and the bulldozers that were scheduled to appear never came. The slum dwellers of Shastri Park, situated between Moti Bagh and Nanakpura on the Ring Road in South Delhi, rained stones on the demolition squads who beat a hasty retreat. Various colonies housing leprosy patients have resisted demolition several times over two decades. In 1986, some of the jhuggies of Jagatmata Kushtashram were demolished. A sustained protest by the people compelled the DDA to rebuild the broken houses. There are several such colonies that have fought for their space in the city. They also include Satyajivan Kushtashram of Srinivaspuri and Jeevandeep Kushtashram of RK Puram. The last one year has been the worst so far with a series of demolitions taking place on the quiet. Over 15,000 jhuggies that housed around 75,000 people have been demolished. While most of them have not been relocated, the few instances of relocation have forced people to live in even more deplorable conditions akin to a living hell. Around 5000 jhuggies of the Rajiv Gandhi camp near the CGO complex were demolished in early May 2000 amidst fierce resistance by the slum dwellers. Women and children were beaten up and hundreds injured. Only 500 to 600 families were shifted to Modalband near Badarpur. Two thousand families from Haathi Park on Deendayal Upadhyaya Marg who were residing there since 1982 were evicted in June 2000. Prior to this, in February, another 100 families were evicted from the Sadar basti near the New Delhi railway station, and 175 families were evicted in January from Vijay Ghat. Fifty jhuggies were broken in the Okhla village of Jamia Nagar in March. In June, bulldozers razed down 200 jhuggies behind Gagan Cinema in the B1 block of Nand Nagri. Three thousand jhuggies in the Seelampur area were demolished between July to August to clear up space for the setting up of the metro railway project. While only a small section was shifted to Bhalsava, the majority was thrown to the streets. In the same way, 1000 jhuggies were demolished in Shastriya Park near the Purana Pul-Ka-Theka. Eighty families were evicted in July from Kisan basti near Chadangi Ram Akhada at Jamuna Bazaar. In February, 300 jhuggies were demolished from Gautam Nagar basti behind AIIMS. Two years earlier, 1800 families were evicted from this same basti. Some of the evicted families were sent to Papankalan. The 200 families evicted from Harijan camp in Masudpur near Vasant Kunj in May 2000 have not been rehabilitated anywhere. 114 India Infrastructure Report 2002 In September 2000, 250 families were evicted from Ravinder Nagar basti near Guru Govind Singh hospital in Rohini. In February, 100 jhuggies in Preet Vihar and 150 jhuggies in Savitri Nagar were demolished without any rehabilitation. In October, around 230 jhuggies from Kushal camp in Jahangiripuri and 250 jhuggies in JJ camp of Shahdara got demolished. Despite wide protests and campaigns again, the month of November witnessed the demolition of 700 jhuggies near the I.G. stadium at ITO. Three hundred children in the basti school and another 600 children in adjoining schools were affected despite a legal plea for a stay on the demolitions until the following March till their school exams could be over. In the same month, another 700 jhuggies were demolished in Gopalnagar near Kingsway Camp. Some of the families from here were sent to Bhalsava. In the same month again, two entire bastis were removed from Lakhi park and C park of Jahangirpuri, which in itself was set up as a resettlement colony some years ago. In January 2001, 150 jhuggies behind the Mata Sundari College were demolished. Sixty jhuggies were pulled down in Dakhshinpuri. These figures do not represent any final count as the demolition spree continues in Delhi and the majority go unreported in the media. The massive displacement of people to places like Papankalan, Bhalsava, Narela, and Modalbund is no solution because these places lack any basic civic amenities. The plots are not yet demarcated in Bhalsava and people continue to live under tin or plastic sheets in the open and are cut off from any source of work and income. There were slum dwellers from three bastis staying there already when people from another five bastis were literally thrown there to live in similar condition. The arrangement here too is for 10 years only, whereas even in the days of the Emergency slum dwellers were given a lease of at least 99 years. Slum dwellers have always worked against overwhelming odds to obtain water, electricity, toilets, and of course even work for themselves to eke out an existence. To move out to open fields in remote areas and invest all over again is an enormous burden. Needless to say, these people will put in their labour, money, and time to make the place liveable. As soon as the land becomes habitable, the price of the land will go up, and the pressure on it will increase, they will be thrown out once more to begin from scratch, and always be on the run! affordable land for mass housing, and grant of tenurial rights to dwellers. The Court in the present case ignored the earlier judgements42 and directed the authorities concerned ‘to take appropriate steps for preventing any fresh encroachment or unauthorised occupation of public land for the purpose of dwelling, resulting in the creation of a slum’. It laid down the basis for this by saying that ‘the density of population per square kilometre cannot be allowed to increase beyond the sustainable limit. Creation of slums resulting in increase in density has to be prevented’. Calling slum dwellers ‘encroachers’ today and comparing them with ‘pickpockets’ flies in the face of the considered opinion of the very same Court! By bemoaning the inability of the government to clear slums while maintaining silence 42 It was the failure of the government to discharge its constitutional obligation that prompted a case in the Supreme Court challenging the demolition of slums in Bangalore (Karnataka Kolageri NS Sangathana & Ors vs. State of Karnataka & Ors). The petitioners contended that the demolitions were illegal as no alternative accommodation was sought to be provided. They challenged the Karnataka Slum Areas Act as being violative of Articles 14 and 21 of the Constitution. It was argued that the slum dwellers had been made homeless because the authorities had failed to discharge their constitutional and statutory obligations to evolve plans for organized industrial allocation around urban areas; for maximum utilization of the potential of land; and for appropriate rural employment guarantees and measures. The failure of the government to evolve a need-based and not wealth-based housing policy was also pointed out. On these contentions, an order was passed in July 1992 directing the appropriate authorities to look into the grievance ‘after issuing the notice to both the parties and giving them adequate opportunity of negotiating in a conciliatory manner’. on the need for alternative accommodation, the judgement clearly shows the class bias of the state. THE HIGH PRICE OF SURVIVAL Urban planning in India has always had little if any housing plans for workers and migrant labour. Hence, they create their own homes on public land under flyovers, along the railway tracks, on the riverbed, or in the shadows of skyscrapers. And then these bastis become ‘illegal’. All schemes and policies to house them either gather dust or get caught in inter-departmental wrangles or are simply abandoned as soon as they are attempted. The Delhi Slum Policy announced late last year extended the cut-off line for the regularization or relocation of slums from March 1994 to November 1998. It was projected that almost 10 lakhs slum dwellers could benefit from this extension. Ironically, there are two qualifying clauses that undercut this magnanimity of the state. First, the government is going to take a development charge from each jhuggi unit! This negates the amount of investment slum dwellers have already made in their existing structures. The ‘illegality’ of their huts make them victims of local policemen, land mafia, local goons, and municipal authorities all out to extort as much as they can. Right from arranging water and electricity, to toilets in their basti, slum dwellers pay for everything through their nose for not only its cost, but also to appease those who prey upon their condition. In fact, do not slum dwellers have every right to a free house with all basic amenities intact in exchange for freeing up the land for other uses given the current value of the land? Environment and Rehabilitation 115 Secondly, while the Delhi government proposes six lakh slums to be regularized, it speaks in the same breath of relocating these slums if required. The link of work and livelihood to one’s place of residence is crucial. Most slum dwellers work as vendors, hawkers, sweepers, drivers, and domestics in nearby residential areas, markets, and offices. Relocation to far flung areas amounts to destitution as it deprives thousands of their livelihoods. In the Bombay Pavement Dwellers Case in 1985, the Court ruled that Article 21 of the Constitution on the right to life includes the right to livelihood, and since the livelihood of pavement dwellers is linked to their place of stay, removing them from the pavements would be tantamount to deprivation of livelihood and therefore unconstitutional as it deprives them of the right to life. Clearly, along with the right to livelihood, every slum rehabilitation has to be accompanied by access to water, electricity, schools, health services, and proper drainage and sewage systems. The living conditions of those rehabilitated in Papankalan, Bhalsava, and Modalbund not only violates every aspect of law but also treats slum dwellers as a ‘problem’ to be disposed of. Each demolition that takes place with such vengeance in Delhi today is a clear act of abdication by the government of any responsibility or accountability to people. With every demolition and relocation, children repeatedly discontinue school despite the desperate efforts of parents to save enough to send them to school in the first place. The concentration of Muslims, Dalits, and Other Backward Classes (OBCs) is naturally high in bastis since they form the marginalized sections of society. Since slum dwellers form a crucial vote bank for every party that comes to power, keeping them in perpetual anxiety about their dwelling place is the surest means to garner votes. As long as slum dwellers prove to be a rallying point for electoral parties, any party in opposition invariably raises the question of slum demolitions. But none of these parties, when they are in power, live up to the promises made during elections. Finally, in an increasingly right-wing society, bastis are vulnerable to caste and communal violence. The struggle to survive as a community is frequently torn asunder by communal and casteist interests that thrive on dividing the working class. THE STRUGGLE OVER URBAN SPACE Plans, it seems, are violated only by the poor and the powerless. The rich and the powerful simply change them to suit their purposes. The initial norm for a decent living space for the poor in the Master Plan for Delhi, 1962 (MPD-62) was estimated at 80 sq. m per family. This norm was applied in practice in the initial 18 resettlement colonies created by the DDA in the 1960s. As the pressure on land started growing, this was reduced to 25 sq. m for the colonies resettled after the demolitions done during the Emergency. Subsequently, the National Housing Policy, May 1992 (NHP-92) provided that ‘in urban areas, the size of the plot should not ordinarily be less than 25 sq. ms with a provision for permissible built-up accommodation and services on individual or shared basis in a neighbourhood adequately served with community facilities’ (MPD-2001, annexure N-5). By stating that the norm should not be less that 25 sq. m, the NHP, without technically violating the earlier provisions, actually reduced it to less than one-third of the original norm. The MPD-2001 provided for 18 sq. m as the norm. In the most recent instances, as in the case of those resettled in Narela, families have been resettled in a mere 12.5 sq. m. The MPD-2001 itself stated that housing needed to be related to considerations of: (i) affordability; (ii) efficiency of land utilization; (iii) equity (which it defined as social distribution of urban land); and (iv) flexibility. ‘(T)he most appropriate type of general housing would be partially built housing on individual plots of 70 to 80 sq m.’ (Ibid: 121). In cases where these were not possible, as in the case of economically ‘weaker sections’, the Master Plan recommends that single family housing could be provided on a reduced size of plots but should have an individual bath and w.c. About the resettlement colonies and unauthorized colonies, it has little to say by way of norms. However, the Plan does provide for ‘equity’ as an important consideration for Delhi’s land-use planning. When this is read in conjunction with the NHP-92, it is reasonable to expect that people should not be uprooted without making alternative provisions. As per the MPD-2001, the total area of the Union Territory of Delhi is 148,639 hectares (ha) out of which 44,777 ha had been considered within urbanizable limits prescribed in the Plan. According to the 1981 Census, this area accommodates 54.5 lakh urban population. The holding capacity of this land was estimated at 82 lakhs. Since the projections for the year 2001 were that Delhi’s population would be 122 lakhs, the proposal was to, firstly, increase the holding capacity of the given area (44,777 ha) through planned efforts and, secondly, to acquire newer areas for urban extension. In the period between August 1990 and June 1998, the DDA has acquired 5007 ha land which has been converted from rural, agricultural, and recreational use for urban extension. Hazards Centre, an NGO, has calculated that 92.5 per cent of this area was located in the new sub-cities of Dwarka (79.2), Rohini (14 per cent), and Narela (5.6), indicating clearly that the proposed housing was, by and large, not for the poor. Narela is the only place where some recently demolished jhuggis have been resettled in tiny plots. In 1998 the DDA proposed an urban extension 116 India Infrastructure Report 2002 area of another 29,761 ha for accommodating a population of 50 lakhs, which is being considered by the National Capital Region (NCR) Planning Board. The MPD-62, which had envisaged Delhi’s urban growth to cover 44,718 ha land, proposed the land-use pattern as in Table 5.2.1: Table 5.2.1 Land Use Pattern Proposed by MPD-62 Housing Commercial use District and regional parks Government offices Industries Warehousing, etc. Educational, research, and other institutes Circulation 19,182 ha 602 ha 10,602 ha 364 ha 2347 ha 304 ha 1741 ha 9571 ha In this distribution, housing constituted about 43 per cent of the total urban land. Of the 14,000 to 20,000 ha of the newer areas that the MPD 2001 planners wanted to acquire, they set aside about 50 per cent for residential purposes. Housing shortage had been estimated by them to be at around 3 lakh units—including squatters and shelterless, as well as families sharing houses in congested areas. About 20 lakh people have been resettled in resettlement colonies covering an area of 1570 ha. There are another 35 lakhs who live in slums or jhuggi–jhopri colonies which cover an area of about 9.5 sq. km. In other words, over 55 lakh people, or about 38 per cent of Delhi’s population lives in a tiny proportion of the city’s urban area. And most residential areas are reserved for the more affluent sections. Hence, slums invariably come up in industrial areas, railway land, or vacant DDA land. The MPD-62 had in fact, provided for 5 per cent residential area for lowincome housing, but according to one estimate even that was not adhered to. This prompted unauthorized habitation (WWF 1993: p. 83). Population densities vary vastly between areas. In 1991, while the number of people residing in the NDMC area was 6882 per sq. km, the corresponding number for the MCD (urban) area was 16,643. In parts of South Delhi, the density can be 1300 persons per sq. km (ibid: p. 64). The MCD (urban) figures include areas like Defence Colony, Greater Kailash, New Friends Colony, Shantiniketan, Anand Lok, and other such colonies where huge bungalows have relatively few people staying in them. In parts of Old Delhi or East Delhi, on the other hand, the densities are likely to be higher. For instance, in Old Delhi, the average density was approximately 80,000 persons per sq. km in 1981. In one census division it was as high as 166,300 persons per sq. km (ibid). In some resettlement colonies, the density of population was 700,000 persons per sq. km, which is almost 102 times that of the NDMC area. One of the consequences of the incapability of the successive governments to either plan for the working class, or to develop towns around Delhi as counter-magnets, is the inevitable growth of unauthorized colonies. The civic amenities provided are woefully inadequate. For instance, according to a recent study (FICCI 2000) about 55 per cent of the households have access to water only outside the colonies (see Table 5.2.2). The rest depend on shallow hand pumps. The quality of water is poor because effluents seep and contaminate the shallow water table, and epidemics are common. A study conducted by the World Wildlife Fund (WWF) in 1993 says that as against the internationally accepted standard of 302 litres person consumes daily (lpcd), one-third in Delhi receive no more than 38 lpcd. Further, the distribution of water is even more skewed with residents of Golf Links and Sunder Nagar getting 450 lpcd whereas the slums, unauthorized colonies as well as re-settlement colonies have to be content with 15– 18 lpcd! Bath and lavatories are available to only 30 per cent of those settled. Poor maintenance and the non-availability of water, along with an user charge imposed, creates a situation where residents do not find it possible to use even these facilities where provided. This is made worse by poor drainage. Only 10 per cent of the settlements have street lights. While illegal connections are rampant, the total power used by these colonies, as per Delhi Vidyut Board’s (DVB’s) own internal assessment, is no more than 15 per cent of total supply. In this light, the Union Urban Development Ministry’s estimate prepared on the ‘positive’ fallout of factory closure and displacement of lakhs of workers shows that this would result in an availability of 700 mega watt (MW) of power, 50 million gallons of water per day, as well as reduction of 40 million gallons per day (mgd) of sewage disposal. They also believe that this would result in saving Rs 240 cr of revenue loss incurred by DVB because of illegal use of power by units located in residential areas. According to them, this would suffice to provide water and electricity for the new housing suburb coming up at Dwarka which will house 10,000 families. In other words removal of 15–20 lakh workers and their families would help provide for 45,000 people! As for housing people, there is sufficient urban land available in and around Delhi to provide affordable and clean shelter. Nearly 35 lakh people live in just 1000 hectares, which is but 1.5 per cent of the total urban area of Delhi. Most of this land is public land. It is perfectly possible in the name of ‘greater public use’ to use this land for housing the poor. It requires no more than 4–5 thousand ha to provide shelter for 2–3 million persons with a unit size of 75 sq. Environment and Rehabilitation 117 Table 5.2.2 Area under Squatter Settlement in Delhi (as of 31.4.94) Zone No. of jhuggies Central East North South West Other Total 50,286 66,798 120,559 123,957 96,866 15,592 4,74058 Land area in sq. metres 1,006,880 1,353,440 2,413,120 2,480,800 1,938,280 311,920 9,504,440 Source: FICCI (2000); based on data provided by the Slum and JJ Department, MCD. m, which is the minimum required for a family unit. Thus, the current density per acre could be reduced by two-third. Those removed can be provided shelter by acquiring just 3000 ha. This land is already available with the DDA, which, during 1990–8 acquired 5007 ha for urban extension. In fact, if the apex Court as well as the Union and Delhi governments are sincere then some of the land acquired in Narela, Bawana, or Rohini, where industrial units are supposed to be located, can easily be developed to provide affordable and clean shelter. Besides more land can be made available by taking over 68 per cent of the land lying with units closed by the Supreme Court in 1996. Rather than demolishing jhuggi–jhopri colonies, the public land on which they stand can be justifiably used to house the urban working class population. Surely this is in accordance with the principle of ‘greater public good’. No solution would make sense if these shelters come up without proper water supply, toilets, sewage and drainage systems, schools, medical facilities, and transport links. The existing problem of power and water can also be resolved by an equal distribution of these resources. Surely, reducing the consumption of water for the affluent can enable slum dwellers to receive more. In addition, the improvement in sewage facilities can transform slums into clean and healthy colonies. In this way, slums can cease to be the eyesore that upsets the rich so much that they want to wipe them out completely. The following fundamental question must be raised: don’t the poor and working class have a right over the air and water of our land? We have to challenge the very path of development that has alienated the poor of this country from its abundant natural wealth while a handful of people have established their control over it. The motto of ‘clean environment’ is also a struggle for equal rights over our resources. Without that, the slogan of environment would only strengthen the hands of the powerful, as is evident from the politics around the Supreme Court orders (see Box 5.2.4). Ultimately it has to be a question of the struggle to end exploitation. In 1994, there were 4.8 lakh dwelling units (each unit with 4.5 persons, totalling 2,164,180 persons) in a total land area of only 9.5 sq. kms. The total urban area of Delhi is 625 sq. kms. In effect, the total area under slums is no more than 1.5 per cent of the total urban area of Delhi! Box 5.2.4 Who Are The Land Grabbers? Land is simply not the problem. Had that been the case, the government would have acquired the land that it had got vacated by industries in the first round of closures in 1996. The Joint Action Committee of Textile Workers’ Unions of Delhi calculated the value of land occupied by displaced and closed industries on the basis of 32 per cent of the land given to them for commerc ial development with a 100 per cent Floor Area Ratio (FAR). In the event, 32 per cent of the total area of 162,135 sq. ft is commer cially developed, Birla Textile was to generate a profit of Rs 340 crores. The government share would have been approximately Rs 700 crores, according to the land-use package ordered by the Supreme Court. Similarly, Swatantra Bharat Mills and DCM silks were to generate a profit of Rs 700 crores from 441,161 sq. ft and Ayodhya Textile Mills a profit of Rs 225 crores from 1,045,440 sq. ft of land. In these cases, the government share would have come to about Rs 1500 crores and Rs 500 crores, respectively. If the government wanted to really use the land for developing lung spaces as directed by the Supreme Court or for any other purpose, this should have been its priority before it went about displacing ordinary working people. 118 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 5.2.5 Life at Relocation Sites BHALSAVA Bhalsava is four kilometres from Alipur Chowk in north Delhi, approachable by a metalled road from Outer Ring Road (near Jahangirpuri) that takes one to what is commonly described as Bhalsava dairy. Here is flat, open ground devoid of trees or shade, open on all sides to the elements. Beyond the houses of the local farmers lies the area where 20,000 people have been left to fend for themselves. They have been dumped here after the jhuggis they stayed in were demolished, in areas as far away as Garhi, Gautampuri (near ITO), Pashchim Vihar, Sanjay Camp (Rohini), and Ashok Vihar. And many more are slated to be brought here from demolished JJ clusters elsewhere. All those brought to Bhalsava had been staying in their area they were brought from for over ten years. The process had began on 3 November 2000 beginning with Garhi. The most recent to be dumped here are people from Sanjay Camp, brought here on 3 April. They were all assured, prior to being shifted, that they were being taken to an area that was developed with all facilities provided. Not only was this not true but the little that has been made available to them was the result of their protests. The land had not been levelled, no drainage has been provided. The soil retains water, and as a result the area becomes muddy and slushy with the slightest downpour. Since there is no sewage system, the pits dug by people to dispose used water get mixed with the downpour, making one big slush. People live under plastic and cardboard ‘shelters’. Before being brought here, people were asked to fork out Rs 7000. The ‘receipts’ given to them mention this as the ‘amount received towards security and license fee for 10 years’. The same also referred to the plot to be provided to them. The size of the plot varied from 12.5 to 18 sq. metres. That is barely enough to provide a room or two. Not everyone who lived in the JJ cluster could raise this amount. Many borrowed at exorbitant rates of interest. Even then, there are many who still await the allotment of plots after having paid the money. Since the soil is porous, each plot owner had to spend up to Rs 15,000 just to dig and then fill it up to be able to build a house over it. This is to prevent seepage. When that is done another Rs 35,000 is required to build a ‘pucca’ house. Not many have the savings or the borrowing capacity to raise this amount. Thus, even where plots are demarcated, there are raised platforms that stand forlorn. There is no drinking water available. The water provided is salty, and therefore its use even for house construction is risky. The DVB has a supply centre and street connections are there, but power supply is erratic. The nearest hospital is Babu Jagjivan Ram hospital in Jahangirpuri. There is a dispensary in block D1. Only two primary schools have been set up, in tents (in block A2 and D1). These temporary schools have classes only up to Class 5. The older children have to travel to their earlier schools spending Rs 20 to 24 each day. The prospect of continuing school in the next academic year seems bleak for several families who somehow managed to get their children to sit for their final exams this year. The children had to prepare for exams under candle light and are plagued by mosquitoes. As a result, many have discontinued their studies. Instead of the ration price of Rs 9 for a litre of kerosene, they pay Rs 15; for sugar, instead of Rs 14 anything between Rs 16–18 per kg; for atta Rs 8 as against Rs 7 in ration shops; and finally rice costs them Rs 12 per kg as against Rs 10. What is more, the price of fuel made out of dung (gobar ke uple) has more than tripled because the local farmers realize that the people have no choice but to use it both for fuel and as a mosquito repellent. Travel costs of families living here have gone up considerably several times. Bhalsava to Paharganj, up and down, costs no less than Rs 16. The only other option is to board connecting buses from Jahangirpuri. Jobs are scarce in the area, with no industry and little commercial activity of any other kind, and therefore everyone has found their earnings slump. Daily wagers and rickshaw pullers barely manage to get work for even 15 days a month. MADANPUR KHADAR EXTENSION This is actually part of the village Madanpur Khadar behind Sarita Vihar. In January 2001, the DDA resettled several families from Ambedkar Colony jhuggis near Nehru Place bus depot. Most families hail from Bihar and U.P., and many had been staying in Ambedkar Colony for years, some for over 20 years. The DDA charged Rs. 7000 for 22 sq. metre plots and Rs. 5000 for 12 sq. metre plots. People had to invest in even leveling this highly uneven land. For a 12 sq. metre plot, three truck loads of material is needed at Rs 300 per truck, or Rs 900 in total. People have not been told how long they can stay here. They only have a xerox copy of the drafts they deposited with DDA without any receipt or any idea of the duration of the lease. To try to prevent the transfer of allotments of jhuggis, the application form also had to contain a photo of the residents. Also, the DDA officials told them they would get no papers for at least five years to prevent them from selling the plots. But most perturbing is the absence of any idea of security or certainty of residence. Madanpur Khadar is far away from their earlier places of work. The bus to Nehru Place takes a circuitous route and hence is Rs 8 one way. Along with the connecting bus to their place of work (many work in Okhla and Gobindpuri), transport fare can be Rs 20 to Rs 24 per day per person. Some have had to give up work due to the difficulty and expense of commuting. At night, the last bus to this place is at 7 p.m. Anyone who comes after that would have to walk long distances. Even those children who used to attend school still travel to Nehru Place. Though there is a government school nearby, the children could not be admitted Environment and Rehabilitation 119 because they have been unable to get the ration cards for identity. Ration cards are yet to be issued with the new addresses. Those who go to school still have to go to their old government school. Even rations are still procured from Nehru Place. Women trudge there on the first day of each month and get the month’s provisions. There are drains lining the jhuggis, but the drains are uncovered, shallow, and narrow. In the monsoons, the drains would definitely overflow all over. The built-up structures of the houses ought not to cover all the floor area, but given the smallness of the 12 sq. metres plots, the houses occupy all the land given. Hence, they are very close to the drains just outside. No electrical power has been provided officially. There are three contractors in this jhuggi who supply electricity, at the rate of Rs 150 per point per month. Hence, those who ask for one bulb and one fan connection have to pay Rs 300 a month. This is a very high rate for the level of power consumed. We were told that the contractors deposit a lakh of rupees with the DVB, and recover their money through the jhuggi dwellers. Hence, those in the DVB and middlemen profit greatly from these jhuggi dwellers. A tanker comes in the evening. A few have installed hand-pumps, but the water is hard water, unfit for drinking. There is a row of mobile toilets at one end of the settlement, but few use that. Most go out into the fields. There is also the complete absence of any health services for miles around. The fly ash emitted by the chimneys of the NTPC’s (National Thermal Power Corporation) Badarpur Thermal Power Station on Mathura Road is a continuous nuisance. It is also a dust-prone area with lots of construction taking place in the vicinity. Both Bhalsava and Madanpur Khadar are transit camps since the arrangement is valid for only 10 years (several respondents said five years) whereas even in the days of the Emergency slum dwellers were given a lease of 99 years. 5.3 RAILWAY SLUMS IN MUMBAI Prem K. Kalra and P. Nandini Kumar Slums create many problems both for the governments whose land is illegally occupied and for the slum dwellers living in a state of uncertainty and an appalling living environment. Eviction, resettlement, and slum improvement are possible approaches to the problem, but none of them have a universal application. The local situation is very important in the design of a solution. It makes sense to go beyond formal ownership to recognize the ‘rights’ of squatters and go ahead with a pragmatic approach. The basic root causes for the existence and creation of slums are low labour absorbing industrial growth, poor growth, and high inequalities. Similarly, vast distortions in the poor’s access to residential land in the bigger cities, not only due to unaffordability, but also because of land use plans that provide little allocation for the poor’s housing, have been important in creating slums (see Section 5.2). Eviction assumes that the slum dwellers are illegal occupants of the public land and hence have no right to stay, and hence should be evicted. This approach ignores the fact that the problem arose primarily because of the lopsided policies and laws framed ignoring ground realities. The only ‘advantage’ of such a policy is that it provides strong disincentives for those who try to occupy new lands and form slums. Resettlement seeks to shift slum dwellers to less valuable land, often on to the outskirts of the city (where less centrally located land is available), and provide them with the basic infrastructure. A likely problem with this approach is that the beneficiaries cannot find work in the outskirts of the city. Relocation when accompanied by schemes to build reasonable housing could work when the outskirts have much economic dynamism. Inadequate investments in public transportation restricts the scope of this approach. Slum improvement accepts the de facto position that the land has been occupied, often for decades, and tries to legalize the existence of the slum dwellers on it and improves the infrastructure thereon. This is probably the most beneficial for the slum dwellers, but has the danger of encouraging formation of more slums. Indeed, if incomes of slum dwellers do not rise sufficiently for them to be able to ‘afford’ a dwelling, they could rent out the same and occupy other lands to create new slums! GENESIS OF THE MUMBAI SLUMS The city of Mumbai, India’s premier city today and with continuing natural impetus for growth, attracts large numbers of people every day from almost all parts of the country. During the 1960s and 1970s, the immigration, both from within Maharashtra and also from other parts of the country, especially from areas known for drought and poverty with few employment opportunities, has been particularly large. Land in Mumbai has been almost entirely out of the reach of not only the poor but also the middle class as well. Even the upper middle classes find it very difficult to buy a house or flat in Mumbai. Resettlement and Rehabilitation Policy In the early 1990s, the World Bank decided that no project could be cleared without the resettlement and rehabilitation 120 India Infrastructure Report 2002 component. This policy change had an impact upon the Mumbai Urban Transport Project-II (MUTP-II). The Government of Maharashtra (GOM) had to formulate a Resettlement and Rehabilitation (R&R) Policy. A Task Force was appointed for this purpose whose recommendations formed the basis of the MUTP-II resettlement and rehabilitation programmes. The MUTP-II was to be based on (a) minimization of displacement; (b) full compensation to the displaced prior to actual shifting; (c) active settlement, and as far as possible retaining existing community networks. It also stressed the need to involve NGOs in resettlement. Mumbai Urban Transport Project (MUTP) To address the problem of ever increasing traffic, which the existing railway system was unable to cope with, the MUTP was started with the help of World Bank by the state government. The first phase of MUTP (MUTP I) worth $25 million, was funded by the World Bank and consisted of introducing an additional 700 buses, constructing three flyovers at important road intersections, construction and improvement of five bus depots and part of a major workshop for Bombay Electricity and State Transport (BEST), and installation of new microprocessor-based traffic signals at 77 junctions. The second phase, called MUTP-II, envisages replacement of level crossings with road over bridges, signalization and traffic management, subways, road improvements, new roads, additional bus transport and improving the suburban railways. For implementation of rail projects under the MUTP-II, a separate corporation for suburban railways called Mumbai Rail Vikas Corporation (MVRC) has been created as a joint venture of Indian Railways (IR) and the Government of Maharashtra. Mumbai Rail Vikas Corporation The Mumbai Rail Vikas Corporation (MVRC) has a share capital of Rs 25 crores in the ratio of 51 per cent and 49 per cent between IR and GOM. It planned to implement 12 important rail projects worth Rs 4741 crore. Another Rs 400 crore project for rehabilitation and resettlement of 22,000 slum families was to be worked out to resettle the project affected persons. The Problem of Railway Slums Workers immigrating into Mumbai in search of employment found empty railway land on either side of the railway track and started putting up their dwellings on this land. Railway lands had been leased by the state government to railways or were owned by the railways. Over a period, these developed into full scale slums. About half of Mumbai’s population lives in such slums without basic facilities like adequate water, electricity, and sanitation, and of course with no legal right over their dwellings. The policy of the government towards these slums until the 1970s has been that the slums being illegal, the squatters have to be evicted. The policy did not work as the evictees always managed to find another area to settle. The slums occupied this ‘spare land’ meant for expansion, and blocking growth of the network, badly affecting the city’s transportation. The adjoining railway tracks became open latrines, creating health hazards, an overpowering stench, and what is worse, increasing the probability of accidents. The frequency of the trains passing on these tracks is so high that the slum dwellers have to cross the tracks even when they find the train approaching. Almost every day, one or another slum dweller is killed while crossing tracks, often resulting in the motorman being assaulted by angry mobs. The trains slow down substantially near slums to avoid such accidents. Where the slums are closer than 30 feet from the tracks, the safety commissioner of the railways requires trains to reduce speed to 5 kmph. There are 11 to 15 such points on the Mumbai metro rails. The reduction in speed, in turn, reduces the number of trips a single rake (an articulated set of coaches) can make in a day, effectively reducing the number of available trains to the growing population. This results in further overcrowding of the local trains already bursting at the seams. Confronted with these problems and the need to free railway land to expand the services, some success was achieved when several organizations came together to solve the problem. Complete clearance is yet to be achieved, but there are notable successes. The key elements of the approach included: the state government identifying and providing land for resettlement; railways helping to develop the land; the municipality providing the offsite infrastructure; twenty two cooperatives of slum dwellers doing design, construction, and financing; and HUDCO (Housing and Urban Development Corporation Ltd.) giving loans to cooperatives and individuals through NGOs such as the Society for the Promotion of Area Resource Centres (SPARC), National Slum Dwellers’ Federation (NSDF) and Mahila Milan. Organizations The residents of these railway slums formed themselves into an association called the Railway Slum Dwellers’ Federation (RSDF), which is affiliated to the NSDF. The RSDF has been quite active in articulating the needs of the slum dwellers and negotiating in all resettlement programmes. It has also been instrumental in getting the support and cooperation of the slum dwellers for such programmes. The SPARC is a registered voluntary organization established in Mumbai in 1984 as a vehicle to explore ways for city governments to work with poor communities through Environment and Rehabilitation 121 partnerships. Today, SPARC is active in 21 cities throughout India. Mahila Milan (‘women together’) is a network of collectives of women who come together to share experiences to gain recognition in their settlements. It took an active part in the railway slum rehabilitation programmes. The NSDF is a national organization of leaders of slums in India set up in 1974. The NSDF focuses on securing land tenure and basic amenities for its constituents, and organizes them in the cities where they reside. THE STORY SO FAR Bharat Nagar Railways wanted to extend the Harbour Line across Thane to Belapur but there was an illegal settlement of 800 to 900 households on the railway land called Bharat Nagar on the land. All these households were offered government built houses a short distance away for Rs 58,000 each, and all but 150 households who could not afford to pay accepted the offer and moved out. These 150 households were moved to a transit camp and given a piece of land on which they would develop their own houses. They formed the Jan Kalyan Co-operative Housing Society and planned and designed houses of SPARC who arranged for loans at low interest. Borivili In Borivili, 700 families were living within 30 feet of the railway tracks. This created the problem of safety for the slum dwellers and low speed for the railways. As a result of negotiations between the RSDF and the Railways, the RSDF convinced these 700 families to move 30 feet away from the track. A wall was built at 30 feet on either side, and the 700 families moved en masse to neatly laid out plots beyond the 30 feet limit, which developed into a railway slum colony called Pushpa Vihar. This project met the needs of both Railways and the slum dwellers. Trains were running at full speed while children could play safely beyond the walls. After this experiment, 135 families in Bhandup and 100 families in Vikhroli moved 10 feet away from the tracks in a similar exercise. Kanjur Marg The Government of Maharashtra decided to lay the 6th corridor––a strip of Central Railway between Kurla and Bhandup––as a part of the MUTP. The RSDF conducted a survey and found that there were 1910 households in the area. The state government found land nearby to accommodate 1200 households with the idea that as the work progresses, new land would be found for the remaining slum dwellers. The railway slums of Mumbai are one of the toughest problems to overcome and the gain in allowing the Railways to expand is enormous. The lessons are clear and would have been obvious to anyone with a pragmatic bend of mind. Accepting slums as a reality, regardless of their illegal status, seems to be the only way out in many situations. A substantial section of the city’s population live in slums and cannot be expected to ‘vanish into thin air’. The slums grew in cities in the first place because of defective urban planning which ignored the existence of the poor. The slum dwellers themselves do not like living in slums but live there out of desperation. Given a chance, they would rather invest their savings and get a legal permanent structure and lead a safe and more respectable life. Policies like eviction, however, push them to the wall and they either rebel or resettle in some other area. Any process of resettlement and rehabilitation can only be in consultation with the slum dwellers. Transferring them to an area far away from their place of work would not help either, since most women also work in these poor communities. A servant maid or a vegetable vendor, for instance, has to live near middle class localities in the city to attend to work early in the morning. The other large incentive for eliciting their co-operation is legal holding of property, which appropriate resettlement can ensure. Better infrastructure at resettlement sites improves the quality of their lives. More often than not, NGOs are less insulated from and more in touch with the ground realities than government agencies. The slum dwellers tend to talk more openly with the NGOs and express their difficulties. Slum clearance of the variety discussed here is pragmatic, and the gains in such an approach being able to break the gridlock are immense. 5.4 POWER PROJECTS DEVELOPMENT: REVIEW OF SOCIAL AND ENVIRONMENTAL ISSUES Binayak Rath • K Ramakrishnan Over the years, the resistance to displacement of population due to power projects has been increasing because of rising activism both at the political and non-governmental levels. The international funding agencies, such as, the World 122 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Bank, Asian Development Bank (ADB), and others have started demanding detailed consultations with and involvement of those who are directly affected, right from the conceptualization stage of the projects. They have also put pressure on the central government, the concerned state governments, and the developers of such projects to work towards more committed proposals on resettlement and rehabilitation (R&R) to the fullest satisfaction of project affected persons (PAPs). The heightened concern about the displacement of people and other associated issues are adversely affecting the growth of the sector. This paper first examines the environmental and social issues that are faced by the power projects and then suggests a more effective manner of implementing the R&R activity. ISSUES IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF POWER PROJECTS While thermal power projects are normally set up at pitheads of coalfields, hydro power projects are set up at locations where the topography is suitable for a high dam, such as at the source of a river/stream. Thus, most power projects are generally located in remote rural areas. Land is normally acquired in the name of public purposes/interest through governmental action. The acquisition of land for the projects always involves considerable complications due to structural problems associated with the land. The revenue records are invariably out of date. The land value shown on the records is invariably much less than the market value due to wellknown and established reasons. In addition, there may be more than one claimant for a given parcel of land. Many a time, the government as well as the Forest Department also lay claims on plots of land that are in the possession of the individuals. The provisions contained in the Land Acquisition Act for fixing compensation usually leads to conflicts and legal battles. The rate for forest land is normally fixed at a high level by the Forest Department. Since it involves transfer of funds from one government department to another, generally there is no dispute over the price. However, in many cases the prices for fertile agricultural land of the poor farmers are generally fixed at rates that are unacceptable to the project affected families (PAFs). In recent years with increased awareness, active participation of NGOs and social activists, the acquisition of land and involuntary displacement of the people are facing increased resistance. However, neither the governments nor the project developers are still willing or able to propose viable and practical solutions, so that the development of the project not only meets the intent for which it is set up but also ensures that the life of those who are directly adversely affected by the location of the project is better than before, that is, the fruits of development also touches project affected families. Power projects always affect the physical environment of the surrounding area. In addition to loss of flora and fauna due to land acquisition, a coal based thermal project generates a large amount of ash––it is said that a thermal plant in India produces ash, and power is merely a by-product. Indian coals are among the worst in the world with as much as 40–5 per cent ash. The ash generated in rural areas could possibly be utilized effectively for landfills, for construction of roads, and for development of wasteland. However, in and around cities, it only adds to atmospheric pollution. Thermal projects also pollute the water bodies in the vicinity of the project due to mercury/heavy metal (from coal) contamination. Hydro projects raise the issues associated with submergence of huge areas of forests and physical habitats. In spite of these adverse environmental impacts, there is little effort to search for cleaner but costlier modes of generating power because of the low value attached to the degradation of environment. Though land is a productive asset (possibly the only one with the rural poor), the compensation offered is invariably lower than its true value. Delays and arbitrary settlement of land acquisition usually sow the seeds of future problems and complications. Moreover, one time lump-sum payment for the land leads to the cash being frittered away causing deprivation in the future. The meagre amount paid to the land oustees (LOs) as compensation is consumed and not invested in productive assets that can generate income in the future. The difficulties faced by those whose land is not acquired but who live in the same village or in the vicinity are even worse. They do not get any benefit but suffer the negative impact of the project. The statutory technoeconomic clearance as suggest by the Central Electricity Authority (CEA) overlooks the costs that a project could incur in taking care of the environment—physical and socioeconomic. In addition to the above difficulties, the developer of a power project faces several difficulties arising from reasons that include the following: • the multiplicity of government agencies that he has to deal with for obtaining the requisite clearance; • reluctance of financiers to fund the project without statutory clearances and reluctance of government agencies to give statutory clearances without financial closure; • cost escalation due to delays in obtaining clearances; • unreasonable demands from project affected people; and • interference from local small-time politicians. The government has been bringing out new guidelines/ regulations governing the environment from time to time, in particular since the early 1990s. These steps have generally been more in reaction to events and to pacify critics, than Environment and Rehabilitation 123 to meet the genuine needs for a pragmatic and integrated view of large development projects. Some of the measures have led to impractical and even impossible requirements being placed on the projects. An illustrative list of the ‘impossible’ regulations is land for land, providing jobs to all or most displaced people, controlling pollutants to advanced countries’ standards, and 100 per cent ash utilization. Such requirements have caused the need for costly and imported technologies to mitigate the effects and acquisition of more land with consequential effects on the costs of the projects. As a result, the tariffs have been pushed up. The time has come to review the stringency of these regulations so that development does not suffer. In short, power projects, perhaps like all other large developmental projects, face enormous hurdles arising from archaic and apathetic governmental procedures and legitimate concerns for environmental degradation and the impact these projects have on the economic and the social fabric of the project affected communities. MITIGATION MEASURES The progress of development projects has been adversely affected over the past several years due to ‘extreme’ positions taken by those who oppose the current form of development. In the early years of independence, the civil society did not get involved in issues arising from the setting up of development projects. In the last few decades, however, the various movements against one development project or the other have succeeded in focusing attention on the costs borne by those affected and displaced, and served to considerably change the attitude of the government as well as the developers and other stakeholders to improve the rehabilitation packages. These movements have, however, degenerated into aggressive environmentalism, based on exotic ideas that ignore the local realities and the desperate need for fast paced development for a poor nation. The combination of democratic rights and the gullibility of the poor has become a potent weapon in the hands of these activists to slow down, if not stop, development projects. Governments in democratic societies find this opposition difficult to handle. The best way to handle the situation is to ensure that environmental, economic, and social issues are adequately addressed right at the conceptualization stage, in consultation and association with all stakeholders, the local community and PAFs, NGOs, activists, and the local governments. This process of consultations and dialogue between all constituents should be maintained throughout the life of the project. Involuntary resettlement not only engenders feelings of alienation and helplessness, but also tends to adversely affect the prevailing social and economic cohesion. Many a time, projects taken up as rehabilitation measures are not in conformity with the local values and extant systems. Hence, they fail to achieve the desired objectives. Government too tends to push all the consequences of land acquisition and the responsibilities of R&R solely on to the project developer. This is not effective since the government is possibly in a much better position to ensure success of rehabilitation efforts than a private developer. Besides, a large project typically generates impacts that have far wider ramifications. If this is recognized, then there could be other ways of mitigating the negative impact on the local communities. Institutional development is necessary to ensure that development projects meet the objectives. There is no articulated institutional developmental strategy in the country within which the development projects can be planned. Currently, the institutions that are in existence suffer from shortages of staff with necessary skills and experience. The institutional framework also suffers from absence of effective management control systems to evaluate the outcome and performance of people oriented activities. Project developers in India have a tendency, possibly in connivance with the local leaders and local government, to avoid measures to fully mitigate the impact on the physical and social environment. The participation of overseas equity institutions and banks has improved the institutional structure and has generally made the Indian organizations respect the statutory and institutional requirements to protect the environment and the interests of project affected people. The knowledge and skills available with the regulatory agencies (currently, largely governmental agencies) to deal with the complex issues related to EIA (Environment Impact Analysis) and SIA (Social Impact Analysis) studies in a pragmatic and cost-effective manner are extremely limited. The policies formulated and implemented to mitigate the negative impact on the environment and the economic and the social fabric of the region are therefore many a time quite inadequate. Another issue that remains inadequately addressed by policies is the disparity that is created between those affected and those who are not affected by the project. Another major issue in R&R today is the problem of high and inflated expectations. The expectations today may be a backlash of the years of neglect. However, increasingly they have become far more than what can be reasonably met by a project to remain economically viable. Costs, when firmed up at the feasibility stage can be dealt with, but the increasing uncertainties and delays may cause many developers to take steps to avoid the responsibilities. High quality R&R programmes are currently not on the agenda of the heads of the projects. This is essentially because generally the performance of a project head is judged by the yardstick of efficiency in the operation of the plants and not by the efficacy of the efforts to address the concerns of rehabilitation and resettlement. 124 India Infrastructure Report 2002 BUILDING A FRAMEWORK FOR R&R Projects are increasingly being influenced by the cultural orientation of people directly affected by it. Projects now focus on solutions not only to the technical problems, but also to the social issues. Any abatement measure, imposed on or adopted by a developer, has to be practical, feasible, and desirable. It should not and cannot be a substitute or a replication of governmental efforts in rural development. Projects have to ensure that the improvement in the standards of livelihood of the projected affected persons is at least proportionate to the extent of impact the project has on such people. However, given the endemic shortages in our country, there is a larger society beyond those directly affected by the project whose interests too have to be considered. If the efforts to help the project affected persons impose a more than necessary burden on the larger society or create disparities with the neighbouring society, then more problems are likely to be created in the long run. There is therefore a need to evaluate various demands and costs more holistically. What is required is a paradigm shift from government diktats through legislative requirements to one of consultation and working in an integrated manner. This calls for a multipronged approach, one driven with a missionary zeal. While organizations have to accept that it should be a mission of the organization to resettle and rehabilitate the people in an equitable and fair manner so as to help improve the quality of those involuntarily affected, it should equally be necessary to keep in view the requirements of the larger society while determining the expectations on the developers. In our suggested framework, the developers are seen as facilitators and not as providers of the services required for R&R of the PAPs. It would be more appropriate for the developer to provide funds for the same purpose to a ‘service provider’ who is qualified, approved, and registered with the government agencies to take up such services. The service provider should undertake the R&R activities in a professional manner in collaboration with the PAFs/PAPs and NGOs. A specified percentage of the project cost should be set aside so that project developers know their costs and accordingly decide on the viability of the project. While a part of this corpus could be used for initial expenses and investments, the balance could be kept aside to meet recurring expenses. This can be used to sustain the families while they are being trained or empowered to obtain sustainable/ alternative employment. The required services should flow through various arms of the state in collaboration with the developers. More attention needs to be paid, both in the institutional design as well as actual working, to ensure effective maintenance, conservation, and improvement in the facilities provided during the lifetime of the project. Once these are institutionalized with the active involvement of PAPs, the chances of success will increase and the benefits will reach a larger segment of the population. The framework also ought to define the role of NGOs and other voluntary bodies, which get involved in any project. Their skills are put to proper use––as watchdogs of the policies and programmes. The NGOs should also play a major role is eliciting the commitment, support, and active participation of the local communities and affected families. They should also be involved in capacity building of PAPs to deal with the changes brought about by the project. Involvement of the staff of the organizations at all levels is one critical aspect in ensuring efficacy of the mitigation measures adopted. Various functional specialists should be involved to create better awareness across the organization on what is at stake for the organization. This single step will go a long way in ensuring reduced tension between PAPs and the personnel of the project and hence the developer. Currently, more often than not, the two adopt adversarial postures, since the project employees feel that the problem is not their creation but they are there to just do their jobs, whereas to the PAPs, the employees are seen as representatives of the developer and all their frustration are hence directed against them and their families. RECOMMENDATIONS FOR EFFECTIVE R&R Based on the discussions thus far, we suggest the following framework for improving the effectiveness of the resettlement and rehabilitation activity associated with large development projects: • The developers’ ought to see the R&R efforts as a commercial opportunity and as an opportunity to serve society. The removal of uncertainty about the costs of R&R by freezing the funds commitment at the start of the project would go a long way in changing the mindset. • The monitoring mechanisms for both the physical and social environment should be institutionalized. Involvement of PAPs and NGOs should be formalized through a fair system of seeking their representation. • The facilitators and NGOs should work together to change the attitude of PAPs to a participatory one rather than one of confrontation. The current attitude of PAPs of total dependence on the government and/or on the developers should change to one of self-sustenance and self-support, of course, with the requisite assistance from the developers, the government, and the NGOs. • The fact that all projects take up large-scale plantations as part of the measures to protect the physical environment can enable them to create sustainable employment for selected and needy PAPs in the rearing of trees. Environment and Rehabilitation 125 • Since fuel is a major constraint in the rural areas, this is one requirement the projects should address directly. This will be much more desirable than provision of electricity, which in any case is a relatively high cost resource and should necessarily become an input to PAFs only after other basic inputs such as health care, drinking water, education, and sanitation are made available. • It would be wise to allow the PAFs to participate actively in the design and construction of their new habitats, particularly their personal spaces. The new habitats should contain basic common facilities such as school, health care, water supply, sanitation, and approach roads. It is generally found that most are willing to pay for better services. The PAPs should be trained in management of the common facilities created as a part of the R&R efforts by adhering to the principle of recovering legitimate charge from the users of facilities for maintenance and enhancement of the common facilities. • The PAPs should be educated and trained by NGOs to contribute to the betterment of the environment. They should be motivated, if necessary through use of monetary incentives to seize the opportunities to have sustainable development rather than merely look for immediate gains or benefits. • Finally, the government policies and regulatory structures should be re-examined so as to make them pragmatic and development oriented. The emphasis should be on evolving regulations that ensure that large development projects are commercially viable as well as acceptable to the people. 5.5 THE CNG VEHICLE PROGRAMME IN DELHI B.P. Pundir In India, the first serious measures to control vehicular air pollution started in April 1991 when emission standards for the new passenger cars and two and three wheelers were brought in. These were followed by the emission standards for new diesel vehicles in 1992 and the progressively stricter emission standards were enforced starting from the years 1996 and 2000. In the year 2000, emission regulations were similar to Euro I norms. The Ministry of Environment and Forests, Government of India had recommended these emission norms, and they were notified by the Ministry of Surface Transport, Government of India. The government was discussing still tougher emission norms on the lines of Euro II, III, and IV. These were to be brought in phases over the period from 2002 through 2007. However, some environmentalists perceived that the government was going too slow and was taking a lenient view of the urban air pollution problem. Public interest litigation in the Supreme Court of India resulted in additional measures for enforcement, particularly in the capital city of Delhi and over the period from 2002 the three other metro cities. Notable among the directives issued by the Supreme Court were the use of unleaded gasoline in 1995 and adoption of Euro II norms for the passenger cars from April 2000 itself in Delhi. Unleaded gasoline was introduced throughout the country during 1999 and Euro II norms are proposed for the rest of the country from the year 2002. To combat the high concentration of suspended particulate matter mostly emanating from diesel vehicles operating in the city of Delhi, the Supreme Court ordered, on 28 July 1998, that, (i) All pre-1990 taxis and three wheelers be phased out by 31 March 2000 and replaced by new vehicles running on clean fuels; (ii) All public buses older than eight years be converted to use Compressed Natural Gas (CNG) by 1 April 2000; (iii) The entire city bus fleet operated by Delhi Transport Corporation and private owners to be converted to use CNG by 31 March 2001. Further in its order of 29 April 1999, the Supreme Court directed all diesel taxis to be converted to use CNG unless they meet Euro II norms for diesel. ‘Clean fuel’ has not been explicitly defined thus far, though the Supreme Court in its ruling has directed the use of CNG. In fact, when the concerned fleet operators could not adhere to the deadline of April 2001, the Supreme Court on 26 March 2001, asked the Environment Pollution (Prevention & Control) Authority (EPCA) to define ‘clean fuel’. The EPCA was asked to recommend other possible fuels that could be used as ‘clean fuel’. Diesel with sulphur content lower than 0.005 per cent by mass is being proposed as a clean fuel. Here, it is important to note that the low sulphur diesel is not going to significantly reduce the particulate emissions, unless the diesel engine technology currently in use in India improved. Fuel sulphur contributes about 0.021 g/kW-hr (grams per kilo watt hour) of particulate emission mass for every 0.1 per ceny sulphur in fuel (Singal and Pundir 1996). Thus, even if sulphur from the current diesel fuel containing 0.05 per cent in Delhi is totally eliminated, an average reduction of 0.0105 g/kW-hr in particulate emissions may be expected, which is insignificant compared to average particulate 126 India Infrastructure Report 2002 emissions from the diesel buses operating in Delhi. It may be viewed in the context that the year 2000 Indian norm for diesel particulate emissions for heavy vehicles is 0.36 g/ kW-hr, at the maximum. The older diesel buses could be emitting around 1.0 g/kW-hr of particulate matter. Total elimination of sulphur from the current level of 0.05 per cent of sulphur by mass in Delhi would amount to only 1–3 per cent reduction in particulate emissions. In the rest of the country too, elimination of sulphur completely while retaining the current or older diesel engine technology amounts at best only to a 5–15 per cent reduction in the particulate emissions. This means that the key to reduction in particulate emissions is the diesel engine technology. It may be mentioned that diesel sulphur in the USA and Europe was brought down to 0.05 per cent maximum when the particulate emission standards were lowered below 0.13 g/kW-hr for the urban buses in the USA in 1994. The diesel engine technology at that stage had already advanced to a level that smoke from these vehicles was not visible to the naked eye. This certainly cannot be said about the current Indian heavy-duty diesel vehicles. Use of low sulphur diesel fuel (0.05 per cent sulphur) in such vehicles will serve no purpose. Quick adoption of new diesel engine technology on production vehicles is possible. Then use of 0.05 per cent sulphur diesel fuel would be a worthwhile measure. CNG IN DELHI Phasing out of commercial vehicles, older than a certain age, has been implemented. There was some resentment by operators on account of the likely economic hardships. On the other hand, conversion of commercial vehicles, particularly the buses, to CNG operation has been very slow. The Supreme Court in its order of 26 March 2001 Box 5.5.1 NGV Programmes Elsewhere Natural Gas (including CNG) Vehicle (NGV) programmes are being implemented in over 40 countries, to solve the urban air pollution problem, and also to increase the usage of natural gas, often indigenously available. In other countries vehicle conversion and demonstration trials have been carried out. The extent and success of these programmes has varied considerably. Table B5.5.1 brings out the number of natural gas vehicles on the road c. 2000. Table B.5.5.1 Natural Gas Vehicles on the Road in Certain Countries (Nos), c. 2000 Asia India China Japan Pakistan Malaysia Indonesia Bangladesh Myanmar Thailand South Korea No. of NGVs 45,000 15,000 6684 4000 3700 3000 1000 200 82 22 Other countries Argentina Italy USA Brazil Russia Venezuela Canada Egypt New Zealand Germany No. of NGVs 462,186 320,000 90,000 60,000 30,000 27,542 20,505 19,000 12,000 5000 Source: Duncan (2001). The two largest NGV programmes, in Italy and Argentina, are primarily centerd on passenger cars and taxis. Due to withdrawal of subsidies, in New Zealand the number of NGVs has reduced to just about 10 per cent of its size during the 1980s. In the USA, NGV programme is driven by clean air legislation. About 2000 heavy-duty vehicles operate on LNG (liquefied natural gas), while 80 per cent of CNG vehicles are light duty vehicles. About 2000 CNG transit buses are in operation. As mentioned earlier, in the USA natural gas buses were introduced when the diesel particulate emission standards were lowered below 0.13 g/kW-hr in 1994 and 0.091 g/kW-hr during 1995. For meeting these limits, diesel buses required use of particulate traps, which is a much more expensive technology than the natural gas vehicles and its durability was also not proven. The data for India includes about 20,000 CNG taxis operating in Mumbai. In China, natural gas vehicles form an important component of the vehicular air pollution control strategy. By the end of year 2000, 15,000 CNG vehicles were in operation in some large cities, including Beijing and Shanghai. In general, heavy-duty NGV programmes for heavy duty vehicles have been slow to take off. This is due to high cost of conversions and technology constraints. In Asia, besides India, Thailand has focussed on conversion of buses to natural gas to reduce urban air pollution. Environment and Rehabilitation 127 had allowed six months grace period (upto 30 September 2001) to comply with these requirements. It was to apply only for those operators who had placed, or would place, firm orders for CNG vehicles on or before 31 March 2001 as a replacement of vehicles presently being operated by them. The deadline for placing order for CNG vehicles was subsequently extended by about a month. The Court has further asked the EPCA of NCT (national capital territory), Delhi to examine whether low sulphur diesel fuel could be regarded as a clean fuel. Delhi has in all about 30,000 buses, including contract carriages operating long distance destinations out of Delhi. Of these, approximately 12,000 are more than 8 years old. Within the city, about 10,000 buses are under operation. Three wheelers number around 87,000. Table 5.5.1 gives the break-up of CNG vehicles as on April 2001 in Delhi (for information on NGV Programmes in Other Countries. See Box 5.5.1). By 30 September 2001, at least 10,000 buses were to be converted to CNG or go off the road. DTC (Delhi Transport Corporation) had placed order for 1880 CNG buses by March 2001. Private owners may be lagging behind in this respect. The production capacity of CNG buses in the country at the moment is about 1000 units per month. The CNG buses requirement of Delhi can, thus, be met in about a year’s time if funding for procurement is available. The number of CNG three wheelers and taxis is, however, adequate. Table 5.5.1 CNG Vehicles in Delhi (March 2001) Buses: DTC Private Cars/taxis/vans Three wheelers Number 175 100 11,100 13,500 SUPPLY INFRASTRUCTURE In Delhi, 68 CNG filling stations have been set up. The CNG dispensing stations, depending upon the type of infrastructure employed and forms in which natural gas is available at the site and storage facilities, are categorized as mother, on-line, or daughter types. Mother filling stations compress the natural gas available from the pipeline network at the site to high pressures of 250–300 atmospheres, which is stored in high pressure storage tanks for dispensing to the vehicles. On-line stations directly deliver the natural gas to the on-board vehicle storage cylinders as the gas is being compressed. Both these types of dispensing stations complete filling of gas into onboard vehicle cylinders to about 200–50 atmospheres pressure in a short period of less than 10 minutes even for heavy vehicles. The daughter CNG filling stations on the other hand employ a cascade of high-pressure cylinders filled with CNG at mother stations. Such a system can refuel only small vehicles like three wheelers or taxis, and has a high amount of residual gas at low pressures, which cannot be delivered to the vehicles at the desired pressure. The break-up of different types of CNG filling stations at present in Delhi, including total dispensing capacity, is given in Table 5.5.2. Table 5.5.2 CNG Filling Stations in Delhi (March 2001) Station type Mother On-line Daughter Daughter-booster Total compression capacity (kg/day) Average daily sale (kg/day) 8 13 44 3 196,072 95,000 Although the total dispensing capacity is 196,072 kg per day, yet there are frequent complaints by taxi and three wheelers of long wait extending from 1 to 2 hours43 and not getting CNG at the required pressure as these are mostly served by the daughter stations. To fuel 10,000 buses, with an average operation of 400 km/day/vehicle requires total dispensing capacity of about 1,300,000 kg per day. Thus, by September 2001 the CNG dispensing capacity was to be increased by a factor of 6.5 to service the bus fleet alone for implementation of the Supreme Court orders. Only the mother or on-line CNG filling stations can fuel the buses. About 100 to 125 additional CNG filling stations would be required to meet this demand. The cost of a CNG station varies from approximately $2,00,000 to $1 million (Jones 2001). A CNG dispensing mother station costs around Rs 4 crores excluding the cost of land in Delhi. The experience and the public reaction on implementation of the Delhi CNG vehicle programme so far is summarized below: • Adequate infrastructure was not available for conversion to CNG, particularly the buses • TELCO and Ashok Leyland, the two heavy vehicle manufacturers in India, could not meet the demand of new CNG buses • TELCO and Ashok Leyland were not involved in conversion of old vehicles to CNG operation, and the quality of conversion has not been satisfactory • Bus operators complained of engine overheating 43 Status prior to the events in August 2001, when waiting periods began to exceed days. 128 India Infrastructure Report 2002 • CNG refueling infrastructure is not adequate as consumer complaints of low pressure are many • Long refueling time and hence long queues with waiting period of 1–2 hours • Certification and inspection of converted buses were inadequate. There were reports of use of spurious cylinders resulting in bursting of cylinders and accidents • Three-wheeler operators complaints of high maintenance costs. The overall impressions of the programme have not been encouraging primarily due to poor implementation, planning, and strategy. Several challenges are faced in an alternative fuel programme like the one being implemented in Delhi. CHALLENGES The introduction of an alternative fuel is a complex issue where several facets of the problem are to be addressed. Technical and economic objectives may not be met due to faulty selection of target vehicles and equipment. If the programme aims also at converting the existing vehicles, the programme should target only the vehicles in good mechanical condition and where maximum environment and/or replacement benefits are possible. In Delhi, a company obtained type approval certification for conversion of a 1992 model bus. However, it has been rendered inapplicable, as the buses older than 8 years were withdrawn in the year 2000. The operators, who have deposited advance money to get their fleet converted by this company, have been subjected to avoidable hardships. Many a times, dual-fuel technology is touted as an appropriate technology with the justification that it provides a flexible fuel option. In the dual-fuel vehicles, conventional fuel is partially replaced by the alternative fuel and the vehicle uses both the fuels simultaneously. It is argued that if alternative fuel is not available, the vehicle can be operated on the conventional fuel, hence giving flexibility of operation to the user. However, pollution mitigation being currently the principal objective of such programmes, the dual-fuel option does not provide the necessary environmental benefits. Table 5.5.3 gives a comparison of the typical emission potential of CNG–diesel dual fuel and dedicated spark ignited CNG heavy-duty vehicles (Weaver 1989). It is quite clear that vehicles with closed loop catalyst, as type 4 in Table 5.5.3, give significant reductions in nitrogen oxide and particulate emissions compared to the diesel version and should be considered for Delhi. In addition, carbon monoxide and hydrocarbons, emissions although higher than the diesel version, are still quite low. Technology and infrastructure to manufacture new vehicles to meet the programme targets should be available well in advance, for which adequate lead time is to be provided to the original equipment manufacturers (OEM). Secondly, the manufacturers should be given firm assurance about the number of vehicles required for them to plan the production through a well-planned CNG vehicle phase-in schedule. The concerned vehicle safety and emission regulations and standards are to be formulated in advance. This enables the vehicle manufacturers and companies undertaking conversion jobs to have full information on what standards to follow and meet. In India, such regulations for heavy vehicles were formulated and notified only in February 2000 just about a year before the implementation date. Thus, the time available to the vehicle manufacturers for fine-tuning of the design and to undertake production to meet the mandated targets of CNG vehicle introduction was inadequate. Poorly managed demonstration programmes lead to negative perceptions. Many a times the public and operators perceive the alternative fuels as only an inferior substitute, due to lack of proper public awareness campaign. This perception is further strengthened by poor quality conversion jobs done on demonstration vehicles. Poor performance of the converted demonstration vehicles may cause incalculable harm to any well meant programme that is not planned well. Table 5.5.3 Emission Potential of Engines Engine type 1. 2. 3. 4. Diesel Diesel and NG Dual Fuel TNO closed loop without catalyst TNO closed loop with catalyst Cycle 13- Mode 13-Mode USHD Transient USHD Transient Emissions g/kW-hr HC CO NOx PM 0.46 21.74 4.85 1.36 2.17 17.12 31.64 9.02 13.59 8.15 9.33 1.58 0.54 0.34 <0.013 0.013 Note: NG: Natural Gas; USHD Transient: US Heavy Duty Transient Test Cycle; HC: Hydrocarbons; CO: Carbon Monoxide; NOx: Nitrogen Oxides; PM: Particulate Matter; TNO : TNO (Netherlands Organization of Applied Scientific Research). Source: Road Vehicles Research Institute. Environment and Rehabilitation 129 Co-ordination is the Key Typically, a number of participants and interest groups are involved in the success of such programmes. Fleet operators, fuel suppliers, vehicle manufacturers, regulatory bodies, market administrators and financial services are the main stakeholders, among others. Co-ordination and leadership of all these stakeholders is a major challenge. Suitable environment for market development and balance between demand and supply of services is to be maintained. The programme should receive a clear endorsement of the government to provide necessary confidence for the investors to participate. A central agency to co-ordinate the total development of the programme, creation of technical standards, mentoring and monitoring of various participants, overcoming technical, market, and legislative constraints etc. would significantly benefit implementation of the programme. Fuel Supply Failure to provide an adequate fuel supply infrastructure has resulted in long queues at the few filling stations in Delhi. Nothing could have been more adverse publicity for the programme. There are choices here in terms of higher capital cost of fast filling stations versus low cost but slow rate filling stations, and scheduling—wherein heavy vehicles could use night hours for filling. Ultimately, of course, the option is really to have the lowest operation costs, including the cost of waiting at filling stations, that includes the opportunity cost of a bus or a taxi that has to wait. There is still no recognition of these problems in the implementation process. The production of specifically built CNG vehicles by the OEMs is the best route to vehicle performance, emissions, and cost, relative to conventional vehicles. The potential of cost benefits are most favourable for the heavy vehicles, as the dedicated CNG heavy vehicles can be built at costs comparable to those of diesel vehicles. This would avoid the high cost of conversion and improve the economics of operation. The cost of conversion of existing vehicles today is slated approximately at Rs 4.0 lakhs for a bus. The operator does not see a short payback period for this investment, and hence there is very little voluntary enthusiasm towards the programme. The major constraint for the OEMs, however, is the economic scale of production. If the total demand is around 20–30 thousand vehicles only, with no significant sustained annual demand, it is not economically attractive to the vehicle manufacturers to make large investments for the production of state of art technology vehicles. The creation of infrastructure and trained manpower for servicing is also linked with the total demand of such vehicles and the business opportunities it provides. A long-term energy and transport policy for the country can provide confidence to the associated industries to make the necessary investments in creating fuel supply infrastructure, production of purpose built vehicles with best performance, and service infrastructure. An easier way to motivate bus operators to CNG conversion would have been to provide a fuel price advantage for CNG, say for the next five years. That also would have given clear policy directions to the vehicle manufacturers and energy companies to commit resources to CNG, without too high a policy risk. CONCLUSIONS The conversion of light vehicles to CNG operation has been quite satisfactory. The relatively easy availability of technology and low cost of vehicle have been the primary factors responsible for the high conversion of the light vehicles. However, the rate of conversion of buses to CNG has been nearly insignificant. A study of various alternatives should have preceded the decision taken for CNG conversion. It is unfortunate that the definition of ‘clean fuels’ is being sought now when the CNG bus programme has failed to meet the mandate. This definition should have been available through discussions with technical experts before requesting the Supreme Court, through a public interest litigation, to issue its order in July 1998 on the use of clean fuels in all commercial vehicles by 1 April 2001. Possibly, other options, like advanced diesel engine vehicles meeting Euro III norms etc., could have been allowed in parallel. Once the old buses are being scrapped, the introduction of advanced diesel vehicles with matching fuel could have given the desired effect, of course over a little longer period, at much lower vehicle and infrastructure costs. Sustainability of such a programme would also have been easy. Many cities in the West, having a much larger population of vehicles, are far cleaner than Delhi, without enforcing conversion of all buses to CNG operation. Once the decision on CNG conversion was taken, an institutional leadership could have avoided a system failure. A central nodal agency should have been made responsible to co-ordinate and implement the programme. Presently, the formulation of emission standards is the responsibility of the Ministry of Environment and Forests. The Ministry of Surface Transport notifies the standards, and enforcement of the Motor Vehicle Rules is a state subject. Delays in notification and issuing of standards and in general lack of coordination among these agencies, result in keeping manufacturers in confusion on the standards to follow and comply with. Working through fuels and specific technologies is at best a poor second to notifying realistic emission regulations with seriousness of enforcement and adequate notice for industry, enforcing agencies, and others to get prepared. This is the route that most countries having successful vehicle emission reduction programmes have adopted The choice of technology, engine types, and fuels has been left for the market forces to decide. 130 India Infrastructure Report 2002 5.6 ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT OF LARGE DAMS: A SOCIAL CRITIQUE Bernard D’Mello44 Large dams have contributed in a significant way to extending irrigation and thereby facilitated the spread of the ‘green revolution’ in Indian agriculture.45 In the light of the outcome of the Supreme Court judgement on public interest litigation (PIL) related to the Sardar Sarovar Project (SSP), a part of the Narmada Valley project, we analyse the judgement and its critique by People’s Union for Democratic Rights (PUDR), to focus on the issues it raises with respect to the attitude of the power elite (Mills 1963) and the state towards those who remain unrepresented in the power structure of the society. Even though Environment Impact Analysis (EIA) and Social Impact Analysis (SIA) is prescribed and for large dams, it has been ritualized as a mere appendage to sanctify the process driven by the interest of the elite. The focus of our analysis is on social and environmental aspects of large dams, which is equally relevant for large infrastructure projects entailing endowment redistribution or social impact, in general. Based on our analysis, we are led to conclude on a realistic, but what may seem to some a rather pessimistic, note that the power elite of the country has to go a long way in incorporating the liberal values of pluralism, legalism, scientism, and political equality in its decision-making processes. It is only if and when these values permeate the power elite’s decision-making that EIA and SIA can get truly institutionalized. Otherwise, they may simply remain rituals as pretence of a liberal democratic society. The lack of concern towards some of the positive values of liberalism is but a symptom of a deep malady of the Indian politicaleconomic system. THE NARMADA CAMPAIGN AND PIL46 In this section, we draw on commentaries on campaigns around the adverse environmental and social impact of the Sardar Sarovar Project. At the outset, we must make it clear that we do not accept the characterization of the conflicts that we are analysing here as ‘environment versus development’ conflicts. This is because to us the notion of 44 The author is grateful to Ram Guha and Sebastian Morris for critical comments on an earlier version of this essay. The usual disclaimers apply. 45 This is a social critique of the environmental and social impact of ‘large’ dams and assessments made of such impact. We are not dealing with the question of technical choice between ‘large’ and ‘small’ dams. Much of that controversy reveals widespread technical incompetence on both sides of the debate. 46 See Divan and Rosencranz (2001). development, without any prefix, denotes, in a Polanyian perspective (Polanyi 1944), ‘habitat’––the habitability of the natural environment as well as the security of individuals in their socio-cultural environment––and ‘improvement’– –productivity and economic growth. Development and concurrent ‘underdevelopment’ of the huge order of magnitude caused by the Narmada dams project spurred a social movement of the victims of the project. The Narmada Bachao Andolan (NBA) was formed in 1989, with the coming together of smaller groups in each of the three states, Maharashtra, Gujarat and Madhya Pradesh—groups that organized the victims at the local level. The NBA leader, Medha Patkar, who essentially derives her legitimacy on a moral and charismatic basis, not only won the confidence of the people who were to be adversely affected but also influenced the financial decision-makers and environment lobbyists in Washington and Tokyo against the project. Initially, the Narmada Valley project was to be financed partly by the World Bank, which seemed to have endorsed the project plan, with all its failures. But later under public pressure, the Bank withdrew in March 1993, after an independent commission appointed by it, the Morse Commission was highly critical of the resettlement and rehabilitation policy and practice.47 The NBA now began demanding that the Indian government appoint a commission to undertake a comprehensive review of the project. The jal samarpan or selfsacrifice by drowning, during the monsoon months, has been the most powerful ‘Gandhian’ tactic employed. That was how the NBA forced the central government to announce a review in August 1993, but predictably, the Gujarat government refused to participate. In May 1994, the NBA filed a PIL against the project in the Supreme Court under Article 32 of the Indian Constitution.48 This PIL was filed in the public interest by the NBA to protect the right to livelihood of the adversely affected persons due to the SSP. According to the petitioner, at least 150,000 persons in 245 villages in the submergence zone are/will be badly affected. They are mostly tribal people and other marginalized peoples, being forcibly displaced and uprooted. They are not being given a chance to be heard and are not receiving proper compensation and resettlement. The project authority is going ahead with the project without having completed the studies required to arrive at an EIA and an SIA. It is 47 As per a reviewer with ‘inside information’ there was a subsequent internal report of the Bank questioning the Morse report. 48 Writ Petition (Civil) No. 319 of 1994. Environment and Rehabilitation 131 violating a number of the conditions laid down by Narmada Water Disputes Tribunal (NWDT) on the basis of which a conditional clearance was given by the MoEF. The Supreme Court (SC) judges, Chief Justice A.S. Anand, Justice B.N. Kirpal, and Justice S.P. Bharucha, in the traditions of PIL set by their predecessors, Justice Krishna Iyer and Justice P.N. Bhagwati, had an opportunity to: • Contribute to ensure that the planning, implementation, and administration of similar large projects in the future be obliged by a commitment of the state to the social welfare of the poor and marginalized, and to the preservation of the natural environment • Ensure the required social and environmental corrective actions in the SSP case, with the participation of the NBA as a representative of the poor and marginalized victims of the project. But on 18 October 2000, the NBA petition was dismissed and the court allowed the dam to be built to its full height of 138 metres. (The height of the dam then stood at 88 metres.) There was, however, a split in the three-member bench, with the majority judgement of Chief Justice Anand and Justice Kirpal constituting the verdict in the case. Justice Bharucha differed, but his was the minority judgement. Given the facts and analysis put forward before the court, his judgement was more in tune with the generally accepted tradition of dealing with PIL, established by such judicial authorities as Justices Krishna Iyer and P.N. Bhagwati. Learnings from the PUDR Critique? A reading of the PUDR critique (PUDR 2000) of the Supreme Court judgement seems to suggest the following: • There is no appreciation of the idea of relevant ‘stakeholders’ representation in the sub-groups that the Narmada Control Authority (NCA) was obliged to set up under various directives—the Resettlement and Rehabilitation (R&R) sub-group (formed in response to a Supreme Court directive to a petition filed by B.D. Sharma in 1990), the Environment sub-group (formed as an essential condition for Environmental clearance by the MoEF). This seems to have exacerbated the impasse between the state and project authorities, on the one hand, and the NBA, a representative organization of the ‘victims’ of the project, on the other. • The R&R and Environment sub-groups are unrepresentative when viewed in a stakeholder framework. The sub-group on Relief and Rehabilitation (R&R subgroup) have the Secretary, Union Ministry of Welfare, as its chairperson. The members are government officials and some technical persons. Similarly, the Secretary, Union Ministry of Environment and Forests, chair the sub-group on Environment. Its members are government officials and some technical persons. • When it was proved that these ‘unrepresentative’ subgroups were not doing their job (monitoring rehabilitation in the field; ensuring the implementation of environmental safeguards) sincerely and efficaciously, the SC ordered the setting up of state-level Grievance Redressal Authorities (GRAs) to monitor rehabilitation. A retired judge of the high courts chaired these, and, according to the minority judgement, only these GRAs could be trusted. Yet, now the GRAs have no veto power; they are merely available for consultation by the ‘unrepresentative’ R&R sub-group. • Even after more than two decades (the NWDT ‘settled’ the inter-states dispute in 1978), reasonable data to assess the likely impact on flora and fauna is not yet available. Much remains to be done by way of studies and by way of action about the likelihood of excessive soil erosion from the catchment leading to excessive siltation of the reservoirs. Indeed, an apparent absence or inadequacy of data on some important environmental aspects still persists. The MoEF had abdicated its responsibility and left it to the Prime Minister’s Office (PMO), to ‘clear’ the project on politically expedient grounds. A conditional clearance was given on 24 June 1987 subject to (i) the planning and implementation of environmental safeguards be carried out pari passu (at an equal pace) with the progress of work on the project, (ii) the environmental science and engineering studies would be carried out as per the schedule, and (iii) the catchment area treatment and the rehabilitation be planned so that these will be implemented ahead of the reservoir filling. None of these have been adhered to, as per the minority judgement. • The MoEF issued guidelines for EIA of river valley projects in 1985. But the project was given a conditional environmental clearance by the MoEF without the necessary data with respect to the likely environmental impact being examined and contrary to the guidelines of the MoEF itself, as stated in the minority judgement. • ‘Costs’ such as the loss of forests, the costs of catchment area development, diversion of railway lines, and the ‘costs’ to the persons displaced by the SSP were marked as unknown in a note that the MoEF sent to the PMO in December 1986. The MoEF admitted the impossibility of knowing the ‘costs’ of loss of habitat of other forms of life and the overall loss of biological diversity. More important than the doctored figures that usually get plugged into a social cost benefit analysis (SCBA) is the fact that this method fails to provide an assessment of the distribution of the various likely costs and benefits to different economic classes of persons affected, either positively or negatively. • The Narmada Bachao Andolan (NBA) is pilloried for wasting public money in presumably contributing to time 132 India Infrastructure Report 2002 and cost overruns through its PIL. There is no recognition of the fact that the NBA does represent the interests of the poor among the displaced persons in struggling for their constitutional rights. It seems to me that even some representatives of the highest judicial body in the country thus do not have any respect for the principle of pluralism. This is a democratic recognition that there may be many different kinds of interest groups, individuals, and civil society organizations and government agencies who are concerned and would like to share responsibility, commensurate with the entitlement of a ‘voice’, in issues related to the environment and the livelihoods of persons affected. • The (majority) SC judgement dissociated itself from arbitrating on controversial public policy issues in this case, even though it is generally accepted that the legal system is the ultimate arbiter of conflict. Legislation on environmental matters related to the project in the form of the Environmental Protection Act was passed in 1994 and environmental litigation under that Act could have been allowed in view of the gross omissions by the NCA and the MoEF under the earlier guidelines of 1985. • Over the last decade, the market is being relied upon more and more to direct and inform environmental goals, say by trying to persuade consumers to value the products of so-called environmentally responsible companies more, ceteris paribus. The Narmada Control Authority (NCA) could have ceased the opportunity to at least appear to be environmentally responsible by reaching a compromise with the NBA on freezing the height of the dam at the prevailing (88 m) level and building separate canals to transport water to parched Kutch and Saurashtra, with very restricted withdrawals along the way. • The SC judges could have asked for the environmental issues surrounding the project to be dealt with more on the basis of knowledge of environmental science and engineering and of the social sciences. Instead, the majority judgement took a public administration perspective. An attitude that environmental issues can be resolved by the application of science and developments in science and engineering may have been more acceptable to both parties to the dispute, especially since there seemed to be no other way of arriving at (even an unstable) consensus. • Given the proclivity of Justices Anand and Kirpal to give a virtual clean chit to the project authority that R&R was more or less proceeding according to the NWDT award on the basis of unverified affidavits of the respondents, rationality, logic, and scientific temper took a back seat. Of course, the NBA’s affidavits too were not verified. But given the bias of the Justices to believe one set of unverified affidavits (the respondent’s affidavits) and reject another set of equally unverified affidavits, how could one even expect them to have adopted a way out of the imbroglio as suggested in 10 above. The public administration perspective used by the Supreme Court in deciding on the case raises important issues. In a liberal democratic society, or one which pretends to be as such, the courts are rightly expected to provide some semblance of protection of law to those who may be outside the dominant coalition of the society. Their independence and institutional strengthening is seen as a key feature of such societies. This is particularly important as the power and institutional structures in societies are prone to collusion, nexus formations, and other dysfunctionalities, which require balancing. The worst sufferers of such dysfunctionalities and state failure are the underprivileged, when their interests clash with that of dominant coalition. To take a public administration perspective in a case like that of NBA is either to admit that state failure is impossible or that the perspective of dominant coalition is shared by the court. While the former position is ‘naive’, the latter is reflective of a lack of liberal outlook and acceptance of plurality. EIAS AND SIAS The environmental and social impact analyses carried out in the context of large dams and infrastructure projects has been ritualized in a context where the politicians, bureaucrats, large land owners, and private interests are likely to make any such analyses subservient to their own objectives (see Box 5.6.1, based on part of a study by the World Commission on Dams). In this section, we focus on environmental impact analysis (EIA) and social impact analysis (SIA) and explore the political, legal, economic, and scientific and technological institutions (S&T) and frameworks required for them to achieve the aims of those analyses. We also assess whether such an ‘idealized’ analysis is feasible and the issues and impediments embedded in the political economy of the existing state. What Should a ‘Progressive’ EIA and SIA Be? EIA in the context of large projects like dams is an activity that is designed to identify and predict the impact of a large dam project on the biological, geological, and physical environment and on the health and well being of human beings. The identification and prediction of these likely impacts has to take account of the specific legal framework, the practice of public policy, social welfare programs and operational procedures on the ground. In a decent society, an EIA also has to interpret and communicate the impacts to all concerned, including the likely victims of the project, in the form of information that can be understood by all. Environment and Rehabilitation 133 It is this information which is supposed to be the basis of logical and rational decisions, including amelioration of the victims of the development process, the poor and exploited, as well as other forms of life. What are the conditions under which an EIA can achieve all of this? An EIA should lead to an environmental impact statement (EIS). The process of preparing an EIS necessarily involves public hearings, where the effort should be to involve all those who are likely to be affected by the project. The draft EIS should be widely circulated so that the public and ‘public intellectuals’ have the opportunity to critically review and comment upon it. The final version of the EIS should be published and made available to the public, and should include the comments, critical or otherwise, of all the reviewers. It is at this stage that the EIS should be submitted to the Ministry of Environment and Forests (MoEF) for a decision, after which, only if the project is environmentally approved, may work be initiated on the project. But a provision is still open for PIL brought to the courts. Indeed, carefully designed administrative, procedural, and jurisdictional structures, preferably with a decentralization of responsibility, and through an elaborate screening and public hearings process, can minimize the probability of PIL on environmental and social issues reaching the courts. An EIA necessarily includes an SIA. Social, economic, and demographic impacts, such as displacement of peasants and tribal communities from the land and the forests, their relocation elsewhere, the impact of the project on agriculture in the region, migration, employment opportunities, health, livelihoods, and inequality, may be manifested directly or via the environmental impacts. Further, what happens to land market values? There are aspects of development and underdevelopment that simultaneously occur. The shifts in local population and the labour force, the multiplier effects, forward and in reverse, both of incomes and employment, displacement and relocation problems, the demands on housing, schools, water, sewerage, health and social welfare, recreation, law and order, and social justice have to be assessed. Changes in the intangible aspects of living such as a sense of loss of place, the feeling of disintegration of community, social disintegration, etc. may be equally, if not more, important. We must particularly analyse the changes in the class differentiation of the peasantry that may occur over time with the unequal distribution of the benefits of assured irrigation in the command area. A progressive SIA may have to take account of the likely compositional changes in the above class differentiation of the peasantry as a result of (differential) access to assured irrigation water. It will also have to assess the likely impacts in the labour, land, and credit markets as a result of the adoption of green revolution techniques. In the Indian context, a ‘progressive’ EIA and SIA will also have to be explicitly sensitive to the reality of the institutionalized inequality of caste and gender. Under Indian conditions on the ground, all this is of course easier said than done. In an Indian setting, the institutionalized oppressions of caste and patriarchy limit social and professional mobility in particular ways. One’s social position gets predetermined to a significant degree by the caste and gender one belongs to. In the case of caste, one’s social status itself becomes essentially hereditary. However, it is the rich peasants and big landowners that are generally able to influence the actual distribution of water or compensation on the basis of land for land, and so on. But there would also be location specific unequal distribution of irrigation water depending on whether one’s fields are in the upper, the middle or the tail reaches of the canals. What may possibly happen to the various classes of people, the displaced who were living and earning a livelihood in the catchment and reservoir areas? That again will likely depend on one’s existing class position. The rich peasants, the big landowners, and the traders are likely to enjoy the political patronage of one or the other of the main parliamentary parties. They may arrange deals of land for land, and so on, and in general, may be positively compensated. But the poor peasants and landless wage labourers may be the victims of the process of displacement. An economist may retort that ‘landless labourers perhaps may be the greatest gainers! If they were landless they could not have lost anything. Agricultural production, ceteris paribus, due to the assured irrigation input, goes up by leaps and bounds, creating many job opportunities for such people, also leading for some time to growth in the real wage rate. Further, some more landless labourers would be better off with migration to the irrigated areas’. The point we are making may thus be missed. While capitalist development coerces the poor peasants and landless labourers to respond in ways that the economists may be able to anticipate, the point here is that capital and the state decide the fate of the poor without their consent. EIA and SIA Go Together At a general level, production is a process of transformation of a determinate given ‘raw material’ (in the case of a dam for irrigation, part of the river flow) into a determinate ‘product’ (an assured supply of irrigation water). This transformation is effected by a determinate human ‘labour’ (intervention), using determinate means (capital goods, technology, techniques, and organization). Fundamentally, tangible production is a human–nature interaction, where the former are conscious beings. Because of human consciousness, the knowledge of the production process exists in collective human imagination at the very commencement of the process. Human beings directly 134 India Infrastructure Report 2002 interact with the ‘raw material’, using capital goods, technology, techniques, and organization to transform it into the determinate product. But in doing so, in this human–nature interaction, they effect a transformation of nature and in the process social relations evolve too (Marx 1867, Childe 1942). It is for this reason that an EIA and an SIA need to go together. They are methodologically inseparable, if the desired result is to be achieved. The above would also perhaps dovetail well into the ecosystems approach. Further Methodological and Ethical Issues The above discussion has been pointing at methodological issues and problems. Some of these are quite intractable, like for instance, particular social and environmental impacts may be assessed differently by different social groups. The assignment of implicit weights to the various social and natural environmental impacts may also reflect the class biases of the power elite who take the major decisions regarding large projects. The social benefit cost analysis (SBCA) derives its theoretical framework from the philosophy of utilitarianism. While ‘larger public good’ may be invoked to support decision making, it entails dilemma associated with redistribution of endowments (with all attendant information problems) and non-negotiable (non-economic) aspects of life. Utilitarianism, applied to the process of development and underdevelopment, implies that traditional moral rules can be broken if by doing so they produce a balance of happiness over misery! Further, the methodology is prone to biases of powerful stakeholders creeping in, if those who apply it are in the services of capital or the State. Political, Legal, Economic and S&T Institutions and Structures Matter Environment Impact Analysis (EIA) and Social Impact Analysis (SIA) have to take account of the specific legal framework, the practice of public policy, social welfare programmes, and operational procedures on the ground. The existing political, legal, economic and scientific and technological institutions and structures will also shape the quality of an EIA–SIA. We have to acknowledge the fact that the power elite in control of the process of production and mainstream politics in India have denied fundamental justice, and not just economic entitlements, to poor people. In general, one cannot expect the courts to be very different in dealing with issues that affect the poor in a society that accepts and expects disparities in political power and the distribution of economic resources. The administrative agencies seem to have certain in-built characteristics that in turn have detrimental consequences for the poor who lack the resources and education to pursue their claims effectively. We social scientists often seem to get locked into analysing the administrative, procedural, and jurisdictional structures within and among government agencies. There is a whole technocracy and bureaucracy composed of scientists, engineers, technicians, lawyers, bureaucrats, and politicians interacting with their counterparts in the private contractors and financial institutions, foreign and Indian. The contractors and financiers have their marketing, sales and public relations executives, lobbyists, and fixers who have a specialized knowledge about dealing with government bureaucrats and technocrats, and the politicians, whether in New Delhi or the state capitals. What we think is of essence is not so much the framework within which decisions are taken but the goals imposed by that framework. For the contractors, the big landowners and rich peasants, it is to make as much profit as possible and accumulate capital as rapidly as possible. This suffuses the ideology and values of all the powerful and wealthy ‘stakeholders’. There is an immense complexity in the decision making process of the Indian government at the centre and in the states, with such a large number of personalities participating in the making of decisions on large state-sponsored development projects. The power elite simply functions within a framework, which allows, and indeed encourages, the plunder of the surplus generated. In such a framework, this goal of the power elite—the big landowners, the rich peasants, big industrialists, financiers and traders, the top bureaucrats and politicians—gets operationalized in terms of business interests in agriculture, industry, finance, and trade. The top bureaucrats and politicians representing the government cannot afford to implement policies and programmes that will jeopardize business confidence. In the 1990s, the very success of public policies has come to be judged by the probability that they will enhance business prosperity and promote private investment. The mutuality of interest between the political executive and business has deepened. To us, it is not very surprising to find the Union Minister of Home, L.K. Advani, while inaugurating the restart of the construction of the Sardar Sarovar dam after the NBA’s PIL was dismissed in the SC, sharing the dais with Jaiprakash Gaur of JP Associates, the largest big dam contractor in India. In such a context, it is difficult to envisage that any kind of SIA or EIA, or the processes followed, will be adequate to take care of the ‘unwarranted’ outcomes of development on the poorer sections of the society. CONCLUSION In the Indian, and indeed, labour surplus, low productivity– income, low land–person ratio, capitalist economies, the risk of impoverishment from involuntary displacement due to infrastructure projects like large dams is very high. If Environment and Rehabilitation 135 these infrastructure projects claim to contribute to ‘sustainable development’, then, apart from the beneficiaries, the government and the project authority ought to have an ethical and legal commitment towards the rehabilitation and development of the victims of these projects. Conceptually and for practical purposes, natural environmental and social environmental impacts belong together in an assessment of any impacts of significant change brought about by dam projects. Hence, EIA and SIA go together. One can anticipate a complex web of cause and effect dynamics and multiple order impacts on a community and the natural environment that is triggered by the decision to set up a large dam. The real problem in the context of such large projects seems to be more of institutionalizing EIA and SIA. The practice of the power elite and the state—at the level of the planning, implementation, and administration of large projects, or even in the judicial system when these practices are challenged by pubic-spirited organizations with PIL— suggests that the processes are by and large antithetical to the liberal values of pluralism, legalism, scientism, and political equality. The latter is a mere symptom of a basic malady that came to the fore once again in the 1960s— incipient and open conflict between the rural poor and the agrarian rich, between the industrial workers and the industrial capitalists, and between the agrarian rich and the industrial capitalists. While green revolution strategy promoted by the Indian state may have helped avert disruptions, it created new problems, some of them related to dams that we have discussed here. Are there any solutions that follow? Solutions to problems that have systemic roots can possibly emerge over a long haul in the course of a popular struggle for socialism, a socialism that begins with democracy. The present path of capitalist development—a grab-what-you-can-for-yourself path of growth that is inimical to human beings and to all other forms of life as well—is not the way to proceed if we want a just and humane social order. Box 5.6.1 Large Dams: India’s Experience1 India has over 4000 large dams as defined by the International Commission on Large Dams (ICOLD). Most of these were built between 1970 and 1989. Around three-fourth of these are in the states of Maharashtra, Gujarat, and Madhya Pradesh. The main purpose is generally irrigation, where the dam is a multi-purpose one. Before we come to the social and environmental aspects in the World Commission on Dams (WCD) India case study, a brief comment on the framework of laws, policies, institutions, and procedures2 and financial, economic, and distribution aspects of dams.3 The Land Acquisition Act, dating back to the nineteenth century, allows the state to take over private land for ‘public purpose’. It is very difficult in law to challenge the ‘public purpose’ claimed by the state. Then there is the Official Secrets Act, another legacy of the colonial period, which allows government actions to be veiled in secrecy and denies access to relevant information to the public. Ramaswamy R Iyer and the other authors to the WCD India case study point out that this ‘renders all talk of ‘participatory’ or ‘people-centred’ planning meaningless’.4 But critical appraisal of the Land Acquisition Act and the Official Secrets Act by Ramaswamy R. Iyer is located in the liberal conceptual opposition of ‘state’ and ‘civil society’. Alternatively, however, if one were to start with the diametrically opposite conception that the ‘state’ expresses the particular characteristics of ‘civil society’ and its class structure and relations, then one can possibly get beyond a liberal right critique of singling out state oppressions alone. Pranab Banerjee, who authors the economic appraisal section, seems unfairly selective in his critique. Having chosen to go by social benefit cost analysis (SBCA), he should have mentioned that the positive externalities of irrigation have then rightly to be accounted for and the economic value of irrigation water (not at artificially low water rates) has to be brought in. Similarly, leakage due to corruption, which has little to do with dams per se, say a standard 5–10 per cent cut on capital expenditure inflate the capital costs. Having adopted the same framework of analysis as the power elite does, the WCD India analysts, statements seem to be patently one-sided.5 If one chooses to go by mainstream analysis, then the problem is perhaps not that the choice of large dams in a technical sense may have been wrong. A more relevant statement of the problem may then be the utter (revealed) mismanagement by the Indian state of large dams, project displacement, redistribution, etc. Government processes of decisionmaking have made long gestation projects particularly vulnerable to failure.6 Also, the usual neo-classical ‘choice of technique’ framework views the choice of technique as a technical choice alone. In reality, the choice may also and more importantly, be a social one, exercised by large landowners and rich peasants, contractors and industrialists, and state functionaries to extend their control over economic processes, secure their appropriation and distribution of surpluses, and the control of state property. 1 2 3 4 5 This is a review of the Indian case study on large dams by Rangachari et al. (2000). Ramaswamy R. Iyer, Chapter 3, Rangachari et al. (2000). Pranab Banerjee, Chapter 4, Rangachari et al. (2000). Ibid., p. 207. See also B.D. Dhawan’s more thoroughgoing economic analysis over three decades, in his book Studies in Indian Irrigation (1999), Commonwealth Publishers, New Delhi. 6 Morris, Sebastian (1987), ‘Process of Investment Decisions in the Public Sector: A Study of Delays and Cost Overruns’, mimeo., Institute of Public Enterprise, Hyderabad. 136 India Infrastructure Report 2002 ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACTS7 The relevant questions dealt with are essentially two. Which of the social and environmental impacts were anticipated? For the adverse impacts that were anticipated, what were the steps taken to minimize them and with what effect? The findings are that large portions of the adverse environmental and social impacts were simply ignored. Till 1978, which means we are considering some 2500 large dams that were initiated prior to that year, there was no formal requirement to assess the environmental and social impact. However, two environmental impacts, one that affects the life of the dam, and the other, which negatively impacts on the yields in agriculture, namely a high rate of siltation of the reservoir and severe waterlogging, were of concern. In our view, this may be because the incremental cost of remedial measures was much lower compared to the incremental benefits accruing from such measures. More importantly, such impacts that directly affect the pecuniary interests of agrarian and, indeed, more generally agribusiness cannot possibly be totally disregarded by any ruling class coalition. In 1978, all new dams were required to be assessed for environmental impacts and had to be cleared from an environmental impact consideration angle prior to the start of construction. Despite this, the WCD India case study reports that the 1800 or so dams taken up for construction since then continued to adversely affect the environment. The Department of Science and Technology (DST) specified guidelines for the conduct of EIA. Environment Impact Analysis became a statutory requirement only in 1994 with the modification of the rules of the Environment Protection Act. But by and large the same sketchy guidelines for EIA continue even today, disregarding scientific progress since then (p. 42). Further, a lack of retrospective assessments seems to suggest that there may be less scientific basis in the assumptions made in forecasting environmental impacts in today’s EIAs th an if the actual environmental impacts of earlier dams were studied. These retrospective environmental studies would also have helped in designing better mitigation measures for the present dam projects, as also in correcting the failures of the past at the ear lier constructed dams. Overall, Shekhar Singh and his team who author the EIA section of the WCD India case study fail to provide a penetrating analysis as to why the kind of situation they describe prevails. Also, one is left wondering that if EIAs were indeed carried t hrough and submitted on time, would the decisions and the outcomes have been any different from what actually happened, especially in the absence of protest movements. SOCIAL IMPACTS The WCD India case study finds that many of the adverse social impacts of large dams are either not incorporated or very inadequately reflected as costs in the calculation of the benefit–cost ratio or BCR. Rehabilitation of the displaced people is taken into account since 1978. But here too it is only the financial burden of relocating and resettling the displaced people, more often just the compensation given, that is taken account of in the financial analysis. With respect to rehabilitation the authors state ‘Rehabilitation of project-affected persons is generally treated as a marginal issue that does not deserve focussed attention…’ In this context, one must mention that while there is now at least an official recognition of the right to compensation for the loss of individual property and livelihood, there is still no compensation for the loss of common property resources (CPRs). Data cited in the case study, official data on those displaced, suggests that overall, people belonging to Scheduled Tribes (STs) constitute around 47.1 per cent of those displaced. If we include Scheduled Castes (SCs) who constitute 14.5 per cent of those displaced, then STs and SCs together constitute 61.6 per cent (around 62 per cent) of those displaced (See Tables 5.8 and 5.9, Rangachari et al. ). It may be recalled that this group forms around 24.5 per cent of the Indian population. Further, the authors confirm that big landowners are the main beneficiary of access to irrigation water, as well as the hypothesis of increasing inequality (p. 214), to not only maintain current inequalities but often to exacerbate them. The impression given is that problems in dam building and irrigation systems are problems created by the Indian State itself. A more penetrating analysis might perhaps suggest that these problems have their origins in the way the Indian economy operates. But there is no doubt that these problems are proving extremely costly for the Indian people. 7 Shekhar Singh et al., Chapter 5, Rangachari et al. REFERENCES Afsah, Shakeb, Benoit Laplante and David Wheeler (1996), ‘Controlling Industrial Pollution: A New Paradigm’, mimeo, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. All India Reporter, (1986), SC 180, ‘Olga Tellis Case’. Becker, G.S. (1968), ‘Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76, No. 2, 169–217. Binswanger, H. (1989), ‘Brazilian Policies that Encourage Deforestation in the Amazon’, mimeo, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Brandon, Carter and Kirsten Hommann (1995), ‘The Cost of Inaction: Valuing the Economy-Wide Cost of Environmental Degradation in India’, mimeo, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Chaturvedi, R.G. and M.M. Chaturvedi (1998), Law on Protection of Environment and Prevention of Pollution, Law Book Company, Allahabad. Childe, Gordon (1942), What Happened in History, Harmonsworth. Environment and Rehabilitation 137 Coase, R.H. (1960), ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 3, 1–44. Cohen, M.A. (1998), ‘Monitoring and Enforcement of Environmental Policy’, mimeo, Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University. Das, R.C. (1996), ‘How Effective are the Air and Water Pollution Control Acts’, Indian Bar Review, Vol. 23, Nos. 3 and 4, 171–88. Dasgupta, Partha (1996), ‘The Economics of the Environment’, Proceedings of the British Academy, Vol. 90, 165–221. Dasgupta, Susmita, Mainul Huq and David Wheeler (1997), ‘Bending the Rules: Discretionary Pollution Control in China’, mimeo, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Dembowski, Hans (1999), ‘Courts, Civil Society and Public Sphere’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 34, Nos. 1 and 2, 49–56. Divan, Shyam and Armin Rosencranz (2001), Environmental Law and Policy in India: Cases, Materials and Statistics, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Delhi Janwadi Adhikar Manch (2001a), ‘How Many Firms does Time have Patience for—A Report on industrial Closures and Slum Demolitions in Delhi’, mimeo, New Delhi. —— (2001b), ‘Always on the Run—A Report on the Plight of ‘Slum Dwellers in Two Relocation Sites of Delhi’, mimeo, New Delhi. Gazette of India, Extraordinary (1990), The Second Delhi Master Plan. Duncan, John (2001), ‘Alternative Transport Fuels: Synthesis of Pilot Projects’, Reducing Vehicle Emissions: Fuel Quality and Alternative Fuels, Asian Development Bank, New Delhi. Federation of the Indian Chamber of Commerce and Industry (2000), ‘Resurgence of Urban India: Urban Renewal and Slum Reform for the State of Delhi’, mimeo, FICCI, Delhi. Government of India (1997), ‘White Paper on Pollution in Delhi; With an Action Plan’, Union Ministry of Environment and Forests. Gupta, Shreekant (1996), ‘Environmental Policy and Federalism in India’, mimeo, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi. Gupta, Shreekant (1999), Country Environment Review: India, Asian Development Bank, Manila. Jones, Peter (2001), ‘Environmentally Friendly Fuels’, Reducing Vehicle Emissions, Fuel Quality and Alternative Fuels, Asian Development Bank, New Delhi. Marx, Karl (1867), Capital, Vol. 1, Progress Publishers, Moscow, 1977, 173–6. Mills, Charles Wright (1963), Power Elite, Oxford University Press, New York. Government of India (1992), ‘National Housing Policy 1992’, Union Ministry of Urban Affairs, New Delhi. Pargal, Sheoli, Hemamala Hettige, Manjula Singh and David Wheeler (1996), ‘Formal and Informal Regulation of Pollution: Comparitive Evidence from Indonesia and the US’, mimeo, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Pargal, Sheoli, Muthukumara Mani and Mainul Huq (1997), ‘Inspections and Emissions in India: Puzzling Survey Evidence on Industrial Water Pollution’, mimeo, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Parikh, Kirit, Jyoti Parikh and Raghu Ram Tata (1999), ‘Clean Water: Environmental Governance 1’, mimeo, Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai. Parikh, Kirit, Jyoti Parikh, Raghu Ram Tata and Vijay Laxmi (1999), ‘Clean Air: Environmental Governance 4’, mimeo, Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai. Planning Commission, ‘Evaluation Study on the Functioning of State Pollution Control Boards’, Programme Evaluation Organization, Planning Commission, New Delhi. Polanyi, Karl (1944) The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time, Beacon, Boston, MA. People’s Union for Democratic Rights (2000), ‘“Reality and the Law Seldom Meet”: A Critique of the Supreme Court, Judgement on the Narmada Dam’, Delhi. Rangachari, R., Nirmal Sengupta, Ramaswamy, R. Iyer, Pranab Banerjee and Shekhar Singh (2000), ‘Large Dams: India’s Experience’, World Commission on Dams, Capetown, <http:/ /www.dams.org>. Rosencranz, Armin, Anand Pandian and Richard Cambell (1999), Economic Approaches for a Green India, Allied Publishers, New Delhi. Sankar, Ulaganathan (2001), Environmental Economics, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Singal, S.K. and B.P. Pundir (1996), ‘Diesel Fuel Quality and Particulate Emissions: An Overview’, Society of Automotive Engineers, Paper No. 961185. Steer, Andrew (1996), ‘Ten Principles of the New Environmentalism’, Finance and Development, Vol. 33, No. 4, 4–7. The First Delhi Master Plan, 1 September 1962. Thomas, Vinod and Tamara Belt (1997), ‘Growth and the Environment: Allies or Foes?’, Finance and Development, Vol. 34, No. 2, 22–4. Tietenberg, Tom and David Wheeler (1998), ‘Empowering the Community: Information Strategies for Pollution Control’, Frontiers of Environmental Economics Conference, Airlie House, Virginia. Weaver, C.S. (1989), ‘Natural Gas Vehicles: A State of the Art’, Society of Automotive Engineers, Paper No. 892133. World Bank (1997), ‘Five Years After Rio: Innovations in Environmental Policy’, mimeo, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. World Wildlife Fund (1993), ‘Can the Clock be Turned Back?’, Delhi’s Environment, Status Report. 138 India Infrastructure Report 2002 6 REGULATORY AND CONTRACTUAL FRAMEWORK 6.1 PRIVATE FINANCE TO PRIVATE ENTREPRENEURSHIP Jayanth R. Varma For the last few years, there has been much discussion and agonizing about how to attract private finance to infrastructure. This paper argues that we have so far tried to attract private finance without welcoming private entrepreneurship. The government, while attempting to withdraw from the financing of infrastructure, has sought to retain its decision-making role in the selection, design, and operation of infrastructure projects. This means that even today capital markets have not been assigned much of a role in allocating capital in the infrastructure sector. There has not been much room for entrepreneurs willing to take large risks in anticipation of large rewards. The net effect is that while there have been sporadic successes in attracting private finance to infrastructure projects, there has been little success in transferring the risks of these projects to the private sector. As long as the government continues to assume the principal risks of the projects, the only effect of the so-called private finance is to convert what would have been an immediate borrowing requirement of the government into an off-balance sheet liability. Thus this form of private finance neither contributes to fiscal stabilization nor promotes allocative efficiency. In fact, when the government’s attempts to promote private finance in infrastructure are ill designed or market distorting, the net result might well be negative both for fiscal stabilization and allocative efficiency. On the other hand, private entrepreneurship in infrastructure could give large benefits in terms of fiscal consolidation and allocative efficiency. To achieve this result, the government needs to: • adopt broad-brush non-distorting incentives; and • desist from premature and excessively rigid sectoral regulation. • give the private sector substantial freedom (subject only to very broad guidelines) to identify and design profitable infrastructure projects; Whatever legal form such a contract may take, it is clear that in economic terms, the net result is no different from the government borrowing to finance the project in the There would remain a class of infrastructure projects that the government may consider of strategic importance but which entrepreneurs do not find profitable to implement. These would require direct government support in the form of an outright subsidy (a negative licence fee established through competitive auction) or some form of credit enhancement. But these should be the exception rather than the rule. MARKET DRIVEN RESOURCE ALLOCATION Pitfalls of the Current Approach Most of the attempts to attract private capital into infrastructure have involved inviting private participation in projects that have been identified and designed by the government. For example, the government decides on a road project, lays down the specifications, and calls for bids from the private sector. Typically, in this approach, the private sector bidder demands a traffic guarantee, or even worse, a revenue guarantee in what is euphemistically called an annuity model. At this stage, the private sector bears very little of the demand side risks of the project. Fiscal Deterioration Regulatory and Contractual Framework 139 public sector. The only difference is that the government’s liability in the so-called private sector infrastructure project is off-balance sheet. It is not an immediate liability that shows up as government debt, but is a contingent liability to make good the revenue shortfalls under the infrastructure project. Even if the government had borrowed and built the project itself, it would have had to dip into the tax revenues to service the debt only to the extent that the revenues from the project fell short of the debt service obligations. Private financing of infrastructure in this model therefore offers an advantage to the government only if the revenue guarantees that it provides are less than the debt service obligations that would have arisen under straight borrowing. But the reverse is certain to be the case. Domestic investors regard government debt as risk free and are therefore willing to accept low rates of interest. The guarantees provided under infrastructure projects involve a wide variety of legal, operational, and regulatory risks for which any rational investor would demand a large risk premium. Thus, private sector financing in this model only substitutes low cost debt with high cost off-balancesheet borrowing. If the objective of private financing of infrastructure is the reduction of the fiscal deficit, it should be evident that the current model does not achieve this at all. In fact, substitution of high cost off-balance-sheet borrowing for low cost debt will only increase the fiscal deficit in the long run as this higher cost borrowing is serviced out of general revenues. The headline numbers of fiscal deficit and government debt may show improvement, but this improvement is wholly illusory and is a result of the faulty accounting techniques that are used to measure these quantities. Politicization of the Investment Decision The flip side of this fiscal burden is that the government has not surrendered its role in resource allocation. Projects are chosen and designed not according to the rules of the market economy, but according to the dictates of the political and bureaucratic considerations that underlie resource allocation by the state. Thus, the current model fails to achieve the key objective of de-politicizing infrastructure investment decisions and subjecting them to the discipline of market economics. Public sector infrastructure investment decisions are often guided by the lobbying power of the various political constituencies that influence the decision making process. They often have very little to do with the actual demand scenarios and the true demand–supply gaps in the economy. Unfortunately, these grave deficiencies of the public sector decision making process carry over into the current model of private participation where the private sector has little or no role in the resource allocation process. Unregulated Monopolies The process of tapping private finance tends to run ahead of setting up an adequate system of regulation. In most sectors, regulation was not considered necessary in the past as the service providers were all in the public sector. Private participation under a weak regulatory framework carries with it the danger of creating unregulated monopolies that are subject only to the contractual provisions governing their participation in the infrastructure project. To the extent that these contracts are incomplete or deficient, there is scope for monopolistic behaviour. What is worse is that by the time the sectoral regulator starts functioning effectively, the pre-existing contracts with private sector participants in infrastructure projects could become a barrier to the creation of a fair and effective regulatory regime. Even where an industry has the potential to function in a near-competitive manner, the pre-existing contracts may preclude the adoption of such an industry structure because of the exclusive rights that the incumbent enjoys. REASONS MODEL FOR THE EMERGENCE OF THE CURRENT Given that the pitfalls of the current model of private participation in infrastructure are obvious to any discerning observer, it is clear that there must be some strong reasons for its popularity. Exclusive Government Privileges Quite often when the private sector is invited to participate in some infrastructural activities, many of the related activities are reserved for the government. For example, while private sector participation is being welcomed in power generation, it is not permitted in the distribution of power. A power plant is thus precluded from selling power directly to the consumers, and must perforce rely on a power purchase agreement with the monopoly state owned distributor of power. The power generated is thus insulated from the actual power demand and relies entirely on take-or-pay contracts with the government owned utilities. To take another example, many infrastructure projects are land intensive and rely on land acquisition by the state. Under the antiquated land acquisition laws, the state pays compensation far below fair value in the name of the public interest. The alternative of the private sector buying its land at market prices thus becomes unviable. It is not true that compulsory land acquisition is necessary for even location sensitive projects like roads and railways. The railroad companies in the United States in the nineteenth 140 India Infrastructure Report 2002 century demonstrated that cities and towns would pay large amounts to the railroads to persuade them to lay the rails through their cities. The appreciation of property prices consequent on the completion of a railway or a road is a powerful incentive for landowners to offer a part of their property to the builder on payment of a reasonable compensation. In the telecom sector, government licensing policy has created artificial restrictions on the number of players even where there is no genuinely scarce resource (like the frequency spectrum) to be allocated. This again serves to limit the role of market oriented resource allocation and divert entrepreneurial resources to the more profitable pursuit of capturing regulatory rents. Ideological Commitment In many cases, the reluctance of the government to give up control over the decision making process in favour of the market is driven by the ideological commitment of large sections of the political establishment to the principle of public sector dominance of the commanding heights of the economy. No doubt a large part of this ideological commitment is self-serving as it maximizes the rents that accrue to the political establishment, but at least a part of this commitment is genuine. In either case, this commitment can be expected to weaken in the face of mounting public dissatisfaction with the pathetic state of government provided infrastructure. There is also an ideological aversion to ‘profiteering’. In the highly regulated economy of the past, it was true that large profits were rarely achieved by fair means. There is therefore a tendency to regard large profits as evidence that unethical or corrupt practices have been adopted. It is difficult for large sections of the political establishment to accept that in a competitive entrepreneurial economy, large profits can be the reward for risk taking or innovation. If a significant fraction of projects can fail with large losses, the projects that do succeed must provide sufficiently large profits to make it worthwhile for the entrepreneur to take the risk of failed projects. In the licence–permit raj, the risks of failure were low and consequently the rewards of success did not have to be as high. This is again an area where perceptions would change gradually, as the reality of a competitive economy becomes more apparent. THE WAY FORWARD From Government to Markets The way forward is clearly for the state to withdraw from its earlier role in identifying and designing infrastructure projects. Ideally, an entrepreneur desiring to implement an infrastructure project identified by him would not need too many more regulatory and governmental approvals than he would need to set up a normal manufacturing project. He would make an assessment of demand, prices, and costs, identify projects that appear profitable, and proceed to implement them. He would have to negotiate with private owners or local authorities for various resources needed to implement the project and pay the going market rate for them. Just as there are various competing enterprises negotiating right of way to lay fibre optic cables across the country today, there could be competing enterprises trying to build highways across the length and breadth of the country. Just as competing railroads in nineteenth century America quarrelled among themselves about right of way, about interchange of equipment, about standardization of gauge, and about standard time zones, these competing enterprises may also have their various quarrels. As in nineteenth century America, they would find ways to resolve these disputes through negotiation, arbitration, or litigation. Box 6.1.1 provides a good example of these processes at work. Similarly competing power generating companies would be with each other to set up plants at optimal locations based on demand opportunities and transmission and generating costs. They would compete for business from large consumers of power and would put in place the transmission and distribution infrastructure to reach these consumers. For this they would also compete for right of way. Other entrepreneurs might try to set up the transmission facility on a common carrier model. The role of the state in all of these cases would only be to provide a transparent and neutral regulatory framework within which all these entrepreneurs would operate. For example, the government may well want to lay down safety standards for roads and also impose common carrier obligations on them. Entrepreneurs guided by the profit motive could well be relied upon to decide whether the road should be six-lane or eight-lane as also what precise route it should take. For all this to happen, the government will have to give up many of the controls and exclusive privileges that it has established for itself. There is no reason for the state to do what the market can do as well or better. The political establishment would have to reconcile itself to location decisions being made by market forces rather than on the basis of which location is closer to the hometown of an influential politician. Whether it is willing to do this is an open question. We are so accustomed to the land being acquired by the state for infrastructure projects that we tend to assume that it cannot be done by private negotiations. Boxes 6.1.2 Regulatory and Contractual Framework 141 Box 6.1.1 Standard Times in Nineteenth Century United States The ability of competing enterprises to achieve standardization by private initiative without the help of government interference is best exemplified by the adoption of Standard Times in the United States in the nineteenth century. Stover (1961) tells the story: ‘As the railroads spanned the nation and became a national network after the civil war, they ran their trains with a crazyquilt pattern of dozens of several mean local sun times. When it was noon in Chicago, it was 11:27 am in Omaha, 11:50 in St. Louis, 12:09 pm in Louisville, 12:17 in Toledo, and 12:31 in Pittsburgh. In fact in Pittsburgh there were six different times for the departure and arrival of stations. The train station in Buffalo had three clocks, each with a different railroad time. . . . It was William F. Allen (1846–1915), managing editor of the Official Guide of the Railways and secretary of the Central Time Convention who finally convinced the lines that they should adopt a standard time. His plans, as conceived in 1881, were accepted in October 1883 to go into effect at noon on Sunday, November 18, 1993. . . Public adoption of the new railroad time was general, although one editor did complain that he would rather run his clock on ‘God’s time—nor Vanderbilt’s’. Just before the change, the Attorney General righteously declared that no government department need use the new time until authorised by Congress. The same gentleman, according to a doubtlessly apocryphal story, was astonished when he missed a late afternoon train on the 18th by eight minutes and twenty seconds. Congress officially adopted standard time thirty-five years later in 1918’. [pp. 157–8] and 6.1.3 on US railroads and US oil pipelines respectively provide examples from nineteenth century United States to show how private negotiation actually worked. Broad-brush Incentives The entrepreneurial model of infrastructure development would also require the state to restructure the system of incentives that have been created for the infrastructure sector. To the extent to which the nation faces a shortage of infrastructure and to the extent that these projects have large positive externalities that are not easily appropriated by the developers, there may be a case for government incentives. The need for such incentives should not be overstated. Markets are quite good at finding solutions for many problems of externalities that appear insoluble in the abstract. Nevertheless, there may indeed be a justification for some incentives. The important point is to ensure that these incentives are as non-discriminatory and non-distorting as possible. This would usually require that the incentives be ‘broad brush’ in nature, applying in a transparent and non-discretionary manner to a wide range of projects in the same sector. Many examples of existing incentives that are highly market distorting in nature are given below. These are the kinds of incentives that ought to be avoided. Flexible Regulatory Structure A distinction must be made between the regulatory structure appropriate for mature industries in mature economies Box 6.1.2 Right of Way for US Railroads Cleveland and Powell (1909) describe how the US railroads obtained their right of way and the land for their stations from the individual landholders either free or at moderate prices: ‘. . . the railroads of this country have very generally obtained releases for right of way by donation. . . . Many of the landowners along the route of the Boston and Worcester united to agreement to release the company from all claims for damages or compensation for the use of their land. Others sold their property at a moderate price. The Ohio and Indiana also generally obtained its right of way through donations. The same was generally true of the Sadusky and Mansfied and many other routes of the Middle West. The fact that so many of the people along the route of the New York and Erie owned stock in the company not only made general the free cession of right of way and lands for station purposes, but it also created a sentiment which kept down the prices of materials to reasonable figures. Landholders on the route of the Georgia railroad generally gave the right of way, and also in many instances, timber for the superstructure. [ p. 199–200]’. Cleveland and Powell (1909) also describe how towns often paid the railroad to route the railway through them: ‘Towns situated at some distance from a line of railroad have not infrequently been required to furnish liberal subsidies to the railroads as a bonus before a desired connection or extension would be furnished. In 1856 the people of Mansfield, Ohio applied to the Atlantic and Great Western for terms upon which the road would be extended through their town. In return the directors prescribed a subscription of $100,000 and a right of way and station sites at fair prices payable in stock. Under these conditions, the road was built. . . . The Northern Pacific in 1880, in response to a request for an extension into Superior, promised to build to that town for one-third of the ‘lands, premises and real estate’ in the city, together with a right of way. Hard as these terms were, ‘the town was railroad hungry’ and the offer was accepted [p. 203]. 142 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 6.1.3 Oil Pipelines in Nineteenth Century United States The manner in which independent pipelines were laid in the United States provides a very good example of the ability of the free market to secure right of way under the most adverse conditions imaginable. To begin with, people are naturally worried about the hazards of leakage, fire, and explosions associated with oil pipelines. These fears were much greater in the early days when safety standards had not yet been well established. Second and more important, these pipelines were built in the face of the fierce and determined opposition of the most powerful and ruthless business monopoly of the time—Rockefeller’s Standard Oil. Tarbell (1904) provides a graphic account of the successful struggle of the United States Pipeline Company: ‘Mr. Emery of the United States Pipeline Company] sent his men into the field to get the right of way. They had made a good beginning before the project was known, but as soon as it was rumoured there appeared promptly on the route surveyed, a number of men known to be Standard employees. They too wanted a right of way, the same as Emery wanted. They bought strips of land across his route, they bought up mortgages on farms where rights had already been acquired, and, mortgage in hand, compelled farmers to give them rights. It was an incessant harassing by men who never used the rights acquired—who did not want them save to hinder the independent project.’ Despite all these efforts, Emery succeeded in laying most of the pipeline. However, Emery’s route involved crossing the Erie railroad, and Emery had obtained permission for this from the president of that railroad before beginning the construction of his pipeline. Emery had laid the pipes on either side of the railroad and the time came to join the pipes: ‘Hardly had [Emery’s men] arrived before there descended on them a force of seventy five railroad men armed for war . . . The pipeline men camped near by for three months, but they never attempted to join the pipes. Mr. Emery had concluded . . . that the Erie officials . . . had found that it would be unwise to disturb their relationship with the Standard, and while his men were keeping attention fixed on that point he was executing a flank movement securing a right of way from a point seventy miles back.’ The United States Pipe Line became a reality despite the determined efforts of the most powerful industrial empire of its time, in an environment where in the absence of anti-trust laws, monopolies were free to do very much as they pleased. How much easier it would be today for modern day infrastructure entrepreneurs who have the benefit of competition laws in their battle with incumbent monopolists. and nascent industries in developing economies. In the former case, the regulatory structure is based on the industry structure that has evolved through market forces and seeks to regulate the monopolies that have emerged in this process. Except at points of time when disruptive technologies change this equilibrium, the regulatory structure can be relatively stable. However, in the case of nascent industries in developing economies, the equilibrium industry structure is not clear. Premature regulation can freeze in place inefficient industry structures and inappropriate technologies and remove the incentive for innovation and entrepreneurship. This point is elaborated further later in this paper. Instances of Market Distorting Incentives Currently, the government provides a wide variety of incentives to encourage private sector participation in infrastructure. A large number of these are market distorting in nature as may be seen from the following examples: Discretionary Tax Incentives: The infrastructure sector receives a wide variety of tax incentives. The government allows some entities mainly in the public sector to issue tax-free bonds. For example, the Indian Railway Finance Corporation (IRFC) has issued several trances of tax-free bonds. The difficulties with this tax incentive are manifold. First, it is available principally to the public sector. Second, it is highly discretionary and there is no transparent and objective criterion by which this incentive is extended to different entities. Third, since it is an incentive to the investor rather than to the entity itself, it applies differentially to different investors depending on their tax status and tax bracket. For example, mutual funds and small investors may not be benefited at all. Thus, these bonds tend to be sold to high net worth individuals and corporates as tax saving devices. To a great extent, this kind of incentive weakens the ability of capital markets to allocate resources optimally. Corporate and institutional lenders receive a tax break on interest income received by them from infrastructure companies under Section 10(23G) of the Income Tax Act. This provision has the great advantage of being largely nondiscriminatory as it operates on a transparent definition of infrastructure companies (this definition is discussed in the next paragraph while dealing with the tax holiday under Section 80-IA of the Income Tax Act). However, it is highly discriminatory as regards the lender since the benefit is by and large restricted to corporate entities. Moreover, this benefit has been largely diluted by the government’s interpretation that the tax exemption applies only on the profit (interest spread) earned by the lender and not on the gross interest receipts. Regulatory and Contractual Framework 143 Infrastructure companies receive a tax holiday under Section 80-IA of the Income Tax Act. This is the closest that we have to a non-distorting broad-brush incentive. It uses a broad and transparent definition of infrastructure companies. The tax break is granted to the infrastructure enterprise itself and is thus non-discriminatory as between different kinds of lenders. The entire profits from the infrastructure business are exempt for a period of ten years. Moreover, to deal with long gestation projects where there may be no profits in the initial years, the company can choose to avail of this tax holiday during any period of ten consecutive years in the first fifteen years. The tax holiday is available to the following infrastructure sectors: • A road including toll road, a bridge, or a rail system; • A highway project including housing or other activities being an integral part of the highway project; • A water supply project, water treatment system, irrigation project, sanitation and sewerage system, or solid waste management system; • A port, airport, inland waterway, or inland port; • Telecommunication services1 whether basic or cellular, including radio paging, domestic satellite service, network of trunking, broadband network, and internet services; • Industrial park or special economic zone2; and • Generation, transmission, and distribution of power3. Discretionary Access to Foreign Borrowing: It is axiomatic that in a country with exchange control restrictions on the capital account, the Fisher Open condition does not hold in general. The Fisher Open condition (also known as uncovered interest parity) asserts that, in a regime of free capital flows, the interest rate differential between two countries merely reflects the expected change in the exchange rates between them. There is no advantage to be gained by borrowing in a foreign currency with a low interest rate since that currency is expected to appreciate and the savings in interest cost would be offset by exchange losses. In a country like India that imposes restrictions on capital flow, this condition is not expected to hold at all. In fact to the extent that India is a capital scarce country, the ex-ante costs of foreign borrowing may be lower than that of domestic borrowing, even after adjusting for expected exchange rate changes. This means that access to foreign 1 The tax holiday is not available to companies that start providing telecom services after 31 March 2003. 2 The tax holiday is not available to companies that develop industrial parks or special economic zones after 31 March 2006. 3 The tax holiday is not available to companies that start generation, transmission, or distribution of power after 31 March 2003. borrowing can be a powerful incentive for infrastructure projects. Since many infrastructure projects lack the credit standing needed to access foreign capital directly, guarantees by domestic financial institutions for foreign borrowing also act as very powerful incentives. Again the permission to tap foreign borrowing and the provision of guarantees by domestic financial institutions for this purpose are both governed by highly non-transparent case-by-case approval procedures. Discretionary Access to Restricted Savings Pools: Pension funds, provident funds, charitable trusts, and several other institutions that control vast amounts of investible funds are subject to government regulations that limit their investments to approved trust securities. One would expect the definition of trust security to be based on the principle of investor protection so that contractual savings and other similar savings pools are protected from imprudent investments. In reality, however, the definition of trust security has been an intensely political one in which considerations of investor protection have only a marginal role to play. Bonds issued by public sector bodies have often received trust security status regardless of their creditworthiness. Moreover, since the definition of trust security is left to individual states, there has been a marked tendency to favour securities issued by state government undertakings of the same status. Reform of these regulations that replace arbitrary judgement of a government functionary by objective standards of creditworthiness or credit rating are essential both to protect the investors concerned and to allow the unimpeded play of market forces in resource allocation in the economy. Closure of Existing Infrastructure to Make New Project Viable: One of the incentives being sought by some infrastructure developers is that existing facilities that could compete with the proposed new project should be shut down to make the project viable. A good example is the Bangalore airport project where the developers have been arguing that the existing airport should be closed down when the new airport becomes operational. It is not at all unusual for old airports to be closed down when new airports become operational. But when this is done, these costs are internalized. For example, if the same company owns both the old and new airports, then while evaluating the new airport, the company would factor in the foregone revenues from the old airport in the cash flow computations for the new airport. If they were owned by different companies, the old airport might still be closed on terms mutually agreed between the two. Any payments made to the owner of the old airport would again form part of the project costs for the new airport. It is also possible that 144 India Infrastructure Report 2002 the two companies might decide to compete with each other. There is nothing unfair about such competition any more than there is anything unfair about a new modern factory competing with an old factory whose plant has been fully depreciated. Similar issues are cropping up in many other sectors. For example, expressway builders would like the existing non-tolled highways to be closed once the new tolled expressway becomes operational. What complicates the matter is that since the old airport and the old highway are in the public sector, they might not operate on purely commercial lines. For example, the public sector highway does not charge tolls while the privately built expressway would. This might make the internalization of closure costs more complex. One simple solution would be to privatize the existing facility along with or prior to the private participation in the new project. In fact, it has become increasingly clear in recent years that the unwillingness of the state to privatize existing facilities while simultaneously attracting private participation in new projects causes a great deal of inefficiency and needless complexity. In any case, it should be clear that the closure of existing facilities without explicitly internalizing the costs of such closure in some manner would lead to faulty resource allocation and sub-optimal utilization of existing resources. Anti-competitive Contracts That Make Subsequent Deregulation Difficult: In its eagerness to attract private participation in infrastructure, the government has often offered contractual inducements that impede subsequent privatization and deregulation of the sector as a whole. The power sector is a good example of this where the initial power purchase agreements with take or pay clauses constitute a major obstacle to the eventual creation of a competitive market for power. Such a competitive market would involve power producers selling directly to consumers or to competing distribution companies. New power plants could be built on this model and existing public sector power plants could be privatized on this basis. The difficulty would be with the existing private plants with their power purchase agreements. Even if all other activities of the State Electricity Boards were privatized, they would still have to exist to honour the old power purchase agreements! The lesson is that while attracting private participation in infrastructure, care must be taken to ensure that the contractual terms are fully consistent with the competitive free market regime that would be the end result of all the reforms. If the existing regulatory structure does not permit this, then the answer is to carry out necessary reforms first and then invite private participation on a basis that is sustainable in the long run. EXCESSIVE AND PREMATURE REGULATION Experience of Developed Markets In the twentieth century, it became fashionable to argue that some industries are natural monopolies and must be subjected to government regulation to protect the consumers. The regulatory regime in the United States received a big boost during the New Deal of the 1930s. The United Kingdom set up a large number of sectoral regulators along with the privatization of several stateowned infrastructure undertakings in the 1970s and 1980s. Countries that started privatizing thereafter have often followed the same path. In recent years, however, there has been considerable criticism of the role and functioning of these regulations (see, for example, Martin 1971). The power crisis in California has drawn attention to the antiquated regulatory structures that impede investment in the power sector in the United States (Robb and Sugalski 2001; Taylor and VanDoren 2001). For example, the investment legend, Warren Buffet, announced that he would invest several billion dollars in the sector if the Public Utility Holding Companies Act (Puhca) were repealed (Edmonds 2001). In the United Kingdom also, there has been mounting dissatisfaction with the functioning of the regulators. The independent Better Regulation Task Force submitted a report strongly critical of the sectoral regulators in the UK (Better Regulation Task Force 2001; Haskins 2001). The task force made three key points: • Competition has not developed as much as might have been expected and as a result, the regulations have become too complex. This complexity is confusing and easy to exploit. • There are concerns that the regulatory processes discourage investment. Sectors like energy and telecommunications had high levels of investment at the time of privatization and the bias against investment did not matter. Prices tumbled, costs reduced dramatically, shareholders prospered, and everyone was happy. But telecommunications for example now requires a new wave of heavy investment and nobody seems satisfied with the regulations. • ‘[R]egulatory bureaucracies flourish in the industries, within the regulators’ offices and in the sponsoring departments. The complexity encourages game-playing and leaves consumers confused and suspicious.’ (Haskins 2001). However, the Better Regulation Task Force does not have much to offer in the form of a solution. It does suggest that some of the functions of the regulators should be taken over by the competition authorities. Lurking behind this suggestion is the idea that the utilities are not Regulatory and Contractual Framework 145 that very different from the other industries and that the same competition law that prevents monopolistic abuses in other industries might be sufficient to do the job in the infrastructure sector as well. This is surely an idea that needs to be pursued. More importantly, the report fails to recognize the key problem that the lack of competition that it deplores is probably the result of the regulatory structure that discourages investment. It is hard to see how any new competitor would emerge on the scene if it has no incentives to make the large investments needed to challenge the incumbent. If the putative challenger believes that the regulator would restrict his profits, then he would see too little rewards for waging a competitive battle that succeeds in dislodging the incumbent through lower costs or better service. He would probably look to other industries to apply his talents. On the whole, the report is pessimistic about what can be done: Most important of all, the culture of bureaucracy and game-playing that remains endemic in the management and regulation of these industries can be changed only if we reduce the power of the utility regulators without damaging the rights of consumers. That will not be easily achieved. [Haskins 2001] Effects of Premature Regulation Much of the criticism that the Better Regulation Task Force has directed against the UK regulators is equally valid in the Indian context. What is of the utmost importance in the context of India and other emerging markets is the finding that regulation has discouraged investment. It is investment that we are seeking to promote and if regulation has prevented adequate investment even in a mature market with a well-developed capital market, there is cause for worry. In fact, there is reason to believe that early regulation would have an even more pernicious effect in an emerging market like ours. We are not dealing with mature industries in mature economies where stable industry structures and established technologies make for a relatively static regulatory perspective. By contrast, we are dealing with a situation of considerable flux as both the technology and the industry structure is evolving. Furthermore, we are not dealing with well-established incumbent giants that have achieved sufficient scale and financial standing to withstand a fair amount of regulatory pressure. On the contrary, the fledgling infrastructure companies of our country today may find the capital markets closed to them if the regulators start breathing down their neck. Some of the effects that premature regulation can have in this fluid context are discussed below. Freezes Poor Technological Choices: In the early stages of infrastructure development, the optimal technological choices are not clear and there is a process of trial and error that goes on. At this stage, a regulator could easily impose a variety of constraints that effectively freeze an initial technological choice that turns out to be inefficient. Incumbents who have invested in the wrong technology would lobby with the regulator to prohibit the use of a new technology that is disruptive. The ban on internet telephony in India is a good example of what incumbents can achieve in a friendly regulatory regime. At a deeper level, the point is not whether the regulator gets its decision right or not. The point is that regulators start arbitrating on technology choices that ought to be left to the free play of market forces. For example, there has been a fierce battle in the Indian telecom industry on whether wireless communication should be allowed in the local loop. The entire debate has centred on whether the government/regulator should permit this technology. To my mind, this whole debate is about the wrong question. The question that we should be asking is how did we end up with a regulatory regime where this technology choice became a decision to be taken by the regulator rather than the free market. Rather than debate the merits of WiLL (Wireless in Local Loop) technology, we should be trying to dismantle the rigid system that made this a regulatory question. Discourages Entrepreneurs Willing to Internalize Risk: At early stages of development of an industry, the demand risks and technology risks are much greater than in a mature industry. An entrepreneur wishing to enter at this stage needs mechanisms to contain those risks. The natural thing to do is to internalize the risks as much as possible and to internalize the externalities as much as possible to maximize returns and minimize risks. Quite often, the entrepreneur would want to integrate vertically and extend his operations horizontally. The vertical integration would internalize some of the demand side risks and facilitate their management. The horizontal extension to related projects, products, and services would make it possible to internalize the positive externalities of the core projects by appropriating as much of the benefits as possible. The regulatory framework tends to frown on such ideas because of its focus on narrow projects. With a few exceptions like real estate development alongside highway projects, it does not appear that internalization of risks and benefits has been given much importance in the design of infrastructure projects. In telecom particularly, the tendency to issue narrow licences tied to specific technologies has limited the ability of players to provide a complete package of services to a common market. A recent proposal to permit various telecom companies to offer internet telephony but 146 India Infrastructure Report 2002 prohibit internet service providers (ISPs) from offering this facility is an extreme example of this kind of thinking. Facilitates Regulatory Capture: Regulatory capture is an ever-present threat in any regulatory regime. The risk is, in my view, greater in an evolving industry where the regulator tends to assume a developmental role as well. It is easy for the incumbents to persuade the regulators that various anti-competitive practices that they may adopt are necessary from a systemic point of view to ensure the healthy growth and development of the industry as a whole. In an evolving industry structure, it is not easy for the regulator to make informed decisions on many of these issues. Matters become more difficult when technological uncertainties complicate the decision making even further. Tends to Create Monopolies and Oligopolies: Regulation has the unfortunate tendency to create monopolies and oligopolies in markets that might be potentially competitive. Paradoxically, the resulting non-competitive industry structure becomes the most potent argument for the continuance of the regulator. We have already seen this process at work in the conclusion of the Better Regulation Task Force in the UK discussed earlier in this paper. The task force ended up concluding that the regulators could be reformed only by reducing their powers substantially, but this could not be done since consumers had to be protected in an environment where competition had not developed to the expected extent. The irony of this is that it is the regulators themselves who are responsible for the lack of competition. The report itself pointed out that regulation had discouraged investment, but failed to recognize that since any new entrant would have to make large investments, to discourage investment is to discourage entry. The point is that regulators create barriers to entry, thereby helping to create a market structure that is non-competitive. By this process, the regulators perpetuate themselves. PRO-COMPETITIVE REGULATION In this light, I would argue that the key regulatory objective in any evolving industry in an emerging economy should be the creation of a competitive industry structure in the long run. Once this has been achieved, the competition law would be the principal regulatory framework for that industry. Morris (2000) has summed up the appropriate regulatory stance exceedingly well, and I would merely like to repeat his conclusion: • ‘When growth and technological change is rapid, as it is in the case of telecom (defined broadly), there is little role for the traditional regulatory stance. More than price regulation, what is important is to keep entry costs low and not frown upon consolidations that are cost reducing.’ • ‘In other sectors with slower growth but with the potential for much faster growth than the rest of the economy, it may still be possible to hold back regulation.’ • ‘In less developed countries (LDCs) with as yet little coverage of people, the focus should shift from prices to growth of the service.’ • ‘In sectors with massive undercoverage and a large number of “outsiders” who would typically pay very high prices. . . [a]llowing many kinds of players with little or no territorial or ownership restrictions . . . has a functionality that arises out of increased coverage.’ Morris thinks that in such situations, price deregulation would be a useful transitional phase in which surpluses are invested in the service to produce rapid expansions. Thereafter, traditional price regulation could be adopted. Essentially, it appears from the above analysis that there are two competing dynamic equilibrium situations. The first dynamic equilibrium is characterized by high regulation, low investment, and a non-competitive industry structure. This is the mature utility industry conforming to the US or UK type of regulation. The second dynamic equilibrium is characterized by low regulation, high investment, and an industry structure that is highly contestable, if not actually competitive. This is the more important and more desirable equilibrium from the point of view of an emerging economy trying to attract investment into infrastructure. STRATEGIC INFRASTRUCTURE PROJECTS It is possible that there would remain a set of infrastructure projects that do not attract entrepreneurial interest, but are believed to be of strategic national importance. This situation may arise because of very large externalities that the project developers are unable to internalize. Some infrastructure projects may also have benefits that are not purely economic in nature. A strategic road network for example may have benefits in terms of national integration, military uses, and redistributive effects that go far beyond its direct economic payoff. It is conceivable that the state may want to promote such a project even though it does not attract private sector interest without additional government support. However, even in these cases, it does not follow that the current model of risk transfer to the government is a good solution. Two other options are available. The first is to build the project entirely in the public sector. For projects whose benefits are primarily strategic and whose direct economic payoffs are relatively small, this might indeed be the best Regulatory and Contractual Framework 147 solution. In cases, where the direct economic payoffs are substantial and strategic considerations make a relatively small contribution to the viability of the project, private sector participation is possible with some government support. The important point here is that this support should be provided in a non-distorting and transparent manner. Earlier (IIR 2001), I argued that negative licence fees represent the most transparent and efficient way of supporting infrastructure financing in a mature capital market. I also argued that credit enhancement could also have a role to play in a country with underdeveloped debt markets. I summarize these arguments briefly here. Negative Licence Fee If an infrastructure project has a high social rate of return, but an unacceptable private rate of return, the socially desirable level of investment can be achieved by a transfer payment from the state to the private sector. This is a standard proposition in the economic theory relating to externalities. The theory would also say that the transfer payment should not exceed the amount of the externality itself (the difference between the social and private returns to the project). If this is violated, then projects which earn an unacceptable social rate of return may be undertaken. The negative licence fee arrived at through a bidding process can potentially achieve this transfer payment. The auction process must include a reservation price (or upset price) to set a ceiling on the transfer payment and ensure that it does not exceed the externality. Credit Enhancement There is a fairly large literature that shows that the privately financed infrastructure of the nineteenth century in fact made substantial use of public funds. For example, the United Kingdom was the only large country that did not support railway construction with public funds in that century. In a country like the United States, the federal, state, and local governments provided financial support in various forms. They subscribed to some of the railways’ bonds, they guaranteed the interest on some bonds, and they provided the collateral for many bonds through their land grants (see for example, Eichengreen 1994; Dobbin 1994). All these forms of credit enhancement made infrastructure bonds more easily marketable to domestic and foreign investors. Yet, except in the case of colonial India (discussed in greater detail in Varma 2000), the government support was nowhere near complete. In the nineteenth century, financial markets in most of the North American and European countries were still in the process of development. It is significant that the country with the best financial markets and institutions (the United Kingdom) did not find it necessary to provide any financial support at all.4 Thus the public support reflects the state of the financial sector even more than the unique characteristics of infrastructure projects. This analysis suggests that the principal argument in favour of credit enhancement as a tool for promoting infrastructure development in India is our relatively underdeveloped bond markets. Government support in the form of credit enhancement and related techniques can facilitate the process of developing the debt market by creating a critical mass of borrowers. For example, if the state were to offer to subscribe to one bond for every two bonds that are placed with the public, developers would have a huge incentive to raise bonds on a large scale. If the government were to provide a partial guarantee, then the fillip to the market would be even greater. A partial guarantee may mean for example: • A Brady-bond5 style guarantee of the principal with or without a rolling interest guarantee. • An interest guarantee covering only the gestation period • A guarantee covering only a percentage of the holdings of an investor with or without a monetary cap. It is possible that these techniques need be used only for a few large high profile projects in the initial period. Thereafter, if the debt market gathers steam, subsequent projects may well be able to stand on their own feet without much state support. It is important from a moral hazard perspective to keep the guarantee limited in scope. If the guarantee covers the bulk of the present value of the debt service obligations, the bondholders have little incentive to monitor the project and to make a careful assessment of its creditworthiness. For the capital markets to perform their resource allocation function fairly well, it is necessary that bondholders face sufficient residual risk to take their monitoring role seriously. And as I have emphasized earlier, it is even more important that equity holders bear practically all the demand side risks, technological risks, and operational risks of the project. Political Considerations The cynic would doubtless argue that once the principle of project specific government support is accepted, political considerations, rather than economic merit, would guide 4 ‘The United Kingdom is the only important country whose railways have been developed practically without public aid’, (Dunn 1913). 5 Brady bonds named after the then US Treasury Secretary were created in the 1980s as part of the restructuring of Latin American sovereign debt. The principal value of these bonds was backed by zero coupon US Treasury bonds, so that the principal was effectively guaranteed by the US government. In some cases, a part of the interest was also guaranteed by a rolling guarantee. 148 India Infrastructure Report 2002 the choice of projects for which this support is provided. This is to a great extent unavoidable and inherent in the very notion of strategic importance. However, the provision of this support in a transparent manner would make these political decisions explicit and more easily subject to political accountability. Needless to say, the whole model of infrastructural entrepreneurship is founded on the belief that a large number of infrastructure projects would not need government support and would be governed by market economics. The political process would hopefully be confined to a small minority of infrastructure projects whose strategic importance requires that they be built with government support when the private sector is not sufficiently forthcoming. CONCLUSION After a few years of struggling with somewhat half-hearted efforts to attract private finance into infrastructure, the time has now come to move forward more aggressively. The government must now prepare to relinquish its exclusive role in decision making in the infrastructure and allow much of these decisions to be made by the free play of market forces. This would open the way for private entrepreneurship in infrastructure. The private sector would then bear the risks and reap the rewards of infrastructure projects. The design and location of these projects would follow economic logic rather than the dictates of political considerations. I have argued that the private sector would come forward to build most of the infrastructure that India needs without the government having to bear the risks. Yet a small number of strategic infrastructure projects, that the state considers important, but the private sector does not consider attractive may remain. It is only for these few projects that the state needs to step in either by undertaking the project with public funds or by providing subsidies or credit enhancement. 6.2 THE GUJARAT GAS BILL AND ITS GENESIS Atanu Chakraborty ANTECEDENTS Studies on the demand projections of gas6 reveal that in Gujarat alone, by the year 2007 the demand is likely to be 44 million metric square cubic meter per day (MMSCMD). The dismantling of the Administered Price Mechanism (APM) would allow market prices for gas and its substitute fuels. This would increase the demand for gas in many applications since gas is expected to be cheaper per unit of energy than competing fuels like fuel oil, and possibly coal. It is also clean and easy to use. Significant amounts of gas are traded internationally through long term (price) contracts. Some of these contracts are linked to oil prices, and to baskets of fuels. The spot market for gas is also beginning to develop. The sector can be divided into: exploration or regassification, that is the supplier end; gas transmission, that is the gas trunk lines; and distribution. Distribution would include the spur lines going to a large customer, besides the retail gas distribution network. The last two parts of the business constitute the gas infrastructure, and are capital intensive. Gujarat has been one of the largest users of gas and has the highest registered demand in the country. The need to develop the sector and its structure was felt in 1998. 6 Natural gas, regassified liquified natural gas or natural gas piped from wells. Since gas infrastructure involves large investments and a large part of the financial resources had to be raised from the market, it was imperative to put in place a framework that would bring the private sector in. The framework also had to allow the risks to be appropriately segregated, to enable subsequent correct attribution and sharing of the risk. Gujarat had taken up port privatization in an ambitious way in 1995. LNG became a favoured cargo for the port operators, which meant that downstream investment in gas using industries was likely. Hence, there was a need to put in place the gas infrastructure7. Furthermore, the fertilizer and power plants in the state were starved of gas as the HBJ line carried a large quantum of the available gas up north. The number of gas suppliers was bound to increase as the monopoly of GAIL was to end. The Challenge The Gujarat Infrastructure Development Board and the Gujarat State Petroleum Company initiated the legal framework for the sector. Some of the considerations and needs that were recognized in the framework were as follows: (a) The resultant gas infrastructure had to be neutral between both suppliers as well the user. This meant that the sector had to segregated. (b) It ought to provide equal access to all users and suppliers. (c) The transportation charges have to be equitable and regulated, since the gas Regulatory and Contractual Framework 149 transmission systems have characteristics of a natural monopoly. The entry barriers are high, and contestability is out of question. (d) The need to avoid the waste in duplicate pipelines that competing suppliers could build in, if a common carrier system were not to develop. (e) A regulatory framework for the transmission system and distribution systems was necessary. (f ) A framework for the contracts to be entered between various players in the sector was to be evolved. (g) Development of the other gas market products such as spots, swaps would have to be facilitated etc. Developing the framework for a sector like gas was not easy. There were no ready parallels available from the developed economies such as USA or UK. In these countries, the gas industry had developed much before the regulatory systems were put in place. Not many successful examples were available from other developing countries either, as state owned companies tended to dominate the sector. Such companies were typically vertically integrated across exploration, transmission, and distribution. It was essential to contextualize these developments to a nascent market such as Gujarat. In India too, the near monopoly of the state owned GAIL, had to be contended with. The Issue of Jurisdiction The very first question that came up related to the jurisdiction of the state government in regulating the sector. The constitutional provisions on this issue were very clear. Item 25 in the states list of activities under the Constitution8 clearly stated ‘gas and gas works’. Nevertheless, there were doubts as to how other entries, including the central list, under the Constitution would impinge upon it. The central government was unsure whether the Gujarat government could go ahead with the Gas Act. This was despite the fact that another legislation relating to gas existed on the statute books. Also there was a clear judgment from the Supreme Court on the issue of jurisdiction over gas. Several leading legal luminaries in the country scrutinized the issue and found that the state government indeed had the jurisdiction to legislate on the gas transmission and distribution, on the strength of the entry item 25 mentioned above. FEATURES OF THE Within the state government, the Gujarat State Petroleum Corporation (GSPC), along with the Gujarat Infrastructure Development Board (GIDB), initiated and piloted the development of the legislation to create an unbundled sector. The government set up a separate gas transmission company, in which GSPC is a minority shareholder. Within the government, there was a large measure of support, but the proposed government legislation had go through of scrutiny at multiple levels. The issue was new and there were no ready models or precedents to go by in the country. Much energy and time was spent by officers and others in making the draft Bill and ironing out all the details. The transmission line connects and separates the user and the supplier of gas. Essentially, it creates an open access common carrier form. This means that every supplier can use the transmission line, and the line would simultaneously carry gas for more than one supplier or buyer. Since, the transmission is on the basis of energy delivered at the end points, it really does not matter whether the characteristics of the gas sent into the line by each of the suppliers varies (within certain limits). Volumes pumped in and drawn could differ somewhat as the accounting is in energy terms. This principle ensures a free movement of gas in the transmission line. The transmission entity is entirely independent, having no interests in gas purchase, production, or trade. As such the market for gas buying and selling is rendered competitive. Some of the key features of the Gujarat (Regulation of Transmission, Supply and Distribution) Bill, 20019 are as follows: • It envisions setting up of a three member regulatory authority for the gas sector. Some of the key functions of the regulator are: regulate the charges of transmission; to set and enforce operational standards of safety and environment in transmission and distribution of gas; to adjudicate in disputes between various players such as a specified company, a supplier, or a distribution licencee; to lay down and enforce the principles of common carrier mode of working. Specified Company GAS ACT As mentioned earlier, models from developing and developed countries were studied. The likely stakeholders from the market were involved. Stiff opposition emerged from certain quarters to this scheme, as they perceived the Act to be a threat to their business plans. One must also mention that during the discussions it transpired that a large number of worries expressed were merely initial impressions, and the opposition to the Act melted on sustained dialogue. R-LNG Supplier Gas Transport Agreement User Gas Seller Sales Agreement Regulator Fig. 6.2.1 Gujarat Gas Act: The Actors and Relationship. 150 India Infrastructure Report 2002 • The Act limits the companies that can participate in the transmission of gas, and they would be called ‘Specified Companies’. Initially this activity was sought to be kept in the public sector, as not many private gas transmission entities would have come forward. But, as the private sector showed interest, Section 23(1) of the Act10 which provided for more than one company to participate in the transmission of gas on the ‘Common Carrier ‘ basis was brought in. The charges for the same, were subject to regulation. • The law now prohibits others (than those licensed) to transmit gas. It would thus facilitate the orderly development of the network, regulation, as well as investment in the gas grid. • A clear distinction has been made between transmission and distribution. Transmission is defined as the movement of gas at a high pressure, while distribution consists of activities further from the ‘city gate’ where the pressures would be low and would not exceed 6 kg per sq. cm. • The distribution of the gas, that is taking it off from the transmission line and retailing, is also licensed as per Section 25 (1) of the act. The Commissioner of Gas established under this Act would be the licensing authority. • To ensure a transparent selection of the licensee as well set the commercial and operational terms upfront, the procedure would be as per the Gujarat Infrastructure Development Act, 199911. • The Act also provides for adjudication of disputes between various players. Section 30 of the Act envisages a tribunal to hear appeals against the orders of the authority as well as against any order of revocation of licence. • While the act protects the interests of the existing entities in the transmission of gas, it brings excess capacities available with them under regulation. Any future additions by them in any case would come within the ambit of this law. While the Act was being deliberated upon, the state government set up a company, the Gujarat State Petronet Ltd. (GSPL), to carry out the business of transmission. It is a company that is envisaged as a venture of users and suppliers of gas and thus able to represent the interests of all the stakeholders .Of course, there are existing players such as GAIL and Gujarat Gas Company, but, they will have to alter their business model to fit in to the requirement of meeting the ‘Common Carrier’ principle. GSPL has already rolled out part of the gas grid in the southern part of the state. See Fig. 6.2.1 for a schematic representation of the players as envisaged in the Gas Act. Contextualization There had been some criticism of this law, not on the fundamental requirement of having one, but of some of its provisions. While as mentioned earlier, some criticisms were based on mere apprehensions, it is still worth sampling the main ones: • The regulator is too weak. It is dependent upon the government • Bringing a state sector company in transmission is not in keeping with the winds of time. If one looks at the Act more closely, both concerns would seem to be not so well founded. Removal of a member of the Commission is fairly difficult, and the Act lays out a comprehensive procedure for this. Also there are certain prohibitions on members of the Authority in taking up, after his/her retirement/tenure, assignments which are connected to the gas sector. Transmission being a natural monopoly had to be structured carefully and it was that consideration that lead the state to set up a venture where all the stakeholders are represented. It is not the usual government company, but one that has formal participation of stakeholders. In any case, the Act provides for more than one company to be the ‘specified company’. Every law is born out of the conditions of society, and draws much from the previous experience that the lawyers and opinion makers have with institutions. The Gujarat Gas Act is one such law that in contextualizing sound economic and institutional principles, hopes to take the sector forward. 6.3 CORRUPTION AND GOVERNANCE: INSIGHTS FROM THE LITERATURE Ajay Pandey ‘Up to the time when a huge corruption scandal, popularly labelled “tangentopoli” (Bribe City), brought down the political establishment that had ruled Italy for several decades, that country had reported one of the largest share of capital spending in GDP among the OECD countries. After the scandal broke out and several prominent individuals were sent to jail, or even committed suicide, capital spending fell sharply. The fall seems to have been caused by a reduction in the number of capital projects being undertaken and, perhaps more importantly, by a sharp fall in the costs of the projects still undertaken. Information released by Transparency International reports Regulatory and Contractual Framework 151 that, within the space of two or three years, in the city of Milan, the city where the scandal broke out in first place, the cost of city rail links fell by 52 percent, the cost of one kilometre of subway fell by 57 percent, and the budget for the new airport terminal was reduced by 59 per cent to reflect the lower construction costs’. Tanzi and Davoodi 1998 The anecdotal evidence of increase in costs of providing infrastructure in Italy due to corruption, as pointed out by Transparency International and cited above, underscores the importance of corruption as an important determinant of governance within infrastructure sectors. Though corruption, or use of public office for private gains, is not the only governance issue in infrastructure sectors, it acquires prominence in the context as the state (and therefore, public office) invariably comes into play in policy formulation, implementation, and at times in regulation of these sectors even though they may have been privatized. Corruption, and its consequences as well as determinants, has attracted the attention of several economists and others over the last 40–50 years, as it has often been seen as a distinguishing feature of developing countries, in terms of both intensity and extensiveness.12 This paper reviews the literature on corruption to draw out the issues and implications relevant to infrastructure sectors in the context of a developing economy (See Box 6.3.1). ECONOMIC ANALYSIS EVIDENCE OF CORRUPTION AND The initial arguments put forth in the literature were predominantly in favour of corruption, as corruption, particularly petty bureaucratic one, was seen as ameliorating the economic ills or effects caused by sub-optimal policies and bureaucratic inefficiency,13 that is, red tape. Leff (1964) and Huntington (1968) argued that when a state errs in terms of policy decisions (and lowers social welfare) or when it is inefficient, the optimal level of corruption in the society is strictly positive. These two arguments are also known as ‘second best’ and ‘efficiency wage/speed money’ arguments in support of efficiency enhancing corruption. In addition, some authors have viewed corruption as a ‘Coasean bargaining’ process, through which the bribe taker and bribe giver negotiate their way to an efficient outcome. Later, many authors have critiqued 12 See Bardhan (1997), for a comprehensive review of the impact of corruption on economic development. Also, see Shleifer and Vishny (1993). 13 In the specific case of bribery with waiting, see the review and analysis in Chapter 2 and Section 6.6. these arguments and have pointed out at least three major reasons as to why corruption may never be efficiency enhancing. These are: (a) endogenous characteristics of performance parameters of the corrupt official, that is, the bribe taker himself decides on the quality and quantity of goods and services to be supplied; (b) illegal and, therefore, secretive nature of corruption, which distorts the decisions of the bribe taker as he tries to maximize his payoffs while minimizing the probability of detection and penalty; and (c) poor enforceability of obligations contracted for through corruption. The literature also has analysed the effects of centralized vs. decentralized corruption in an economy and the determinant of its existence and persistence. This section starts with the conceptualization of corruption in the literature and some distinctions invoked, and details the arguments used by both apologists as well as radicals on corruption. Lastly, it points out some evidence, which does point out the negative consequences of corruption on economy. Forms of Corruption Corruption, in common usage, means different things in different contexts, ranging from ‘illegal’ and/or ‘immoral’ acts to ‘misuse of office for private gains’. It is only in the limited sense of misuse of public office (which allows the incumbent to sell property rights over a public resource or allows him the right to buy from private sector) for private gains, corruption is amenable for economic analysis. Political corruption, when the gains are in the form of political capital or for building/nurturing the constituencies of the public official, is not suited for similar treatment. Accordingly, much of what is written by economists (and therefore, in this paper) is limited to corruption where the payoffs line the pocket of the corrupt public official himself. Sometimes, the term ‘political corruption’ has also been used for grand, as opposed to petty, corruption (Tanzi and Davoodi 1998). Grand corruption can be seen as a manifestation of high and centralized corruption, where the public officials at the very top collect payoffs. In the case of petty corruption, the collection of bribes is decentralized and the top of the government is seen as relatively less corrupt. Another useful distinction made by Shleifer and Vishny (1993) is corruption with theft, as opposed to, corruption without theft. Corruption with theft takes place when the bribe taker pockets the entire proceeds of the transaction without parting with anything for the government. A customs official, who charges less than the official custom rate for allowing passage of the goods is an example of corruption with theft, and so is the case when a train conductor allows someone to travel in a higher class compartment, while holding lower class ticket, after accepting a bribe. Unlike 152 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 6.3.1 Why Governance Matters: A World Bank Perspective Praveen Kulshreshtha . . . causes of financial crises and poverty are one and the same . . . (If countries) do not have good governance, if they do not confront the issue of corruption, if they do not have a complete legal system which protects human rights, property rights and contracts . . . their development is fundamentally flawed and will not last. 1 (James D. Wolfensohn) Governance has become an important focal point of debate, discussion, and concern among bilateral aid-donors, aid-recipient countries, and international development agencies such as the World Bank. 2 It is generally recognized as an important determinant of a country’s long-term economic growth and development. 3 The Bank, in its well-known report Governance and Development (1991) defined governance as ‘the manner in which power is exercised in the management of a country’s economic and social resources’. In its update, Governance: The World Bank’s Experience (1994), the Bank viewed governance more broadly and asserted that ‘Good governance is epitomized by predictable, open, and enlightened policymaking (that is, transparent processes); a bureaucracy imbued with a professional ethos; an executive arm of government accountable for its actions; and a strong civil society participating in public affairs; and all behaving under the rule of law.’ The above view of the Bank is shared by most donor countries and major development organizations (such as UNDP, other agencies of the UN, regional development banks, European Union, OECD, WTO, professional and private organizations, and non-governmental organizations (NGOs)). More importantly, the Bank’s governance framework has influenced and shaped the development programmes of various developing nations of the world during the past decade. The framework is not only relevant to the core functions of governments (such as public expenditure management, tax administration, public enterprise and civil service reform, legal reform), but also incorporates governance concerns in specific sectors such as education, health, and infrastructure. This Box highlights the key factors in the World Bank’s approach to governance as they have evolved, especially in the social and infrastructure sectors.4 GOVERNANCE AND DEVELOPMENT ASSISTANCE In its earliest years, the World Bank focused primarily on providing technocratic solutions to development related problems, assuming that sound policies and well-designed projects will yield maximum social benefits when they are implemented by development-oriented governments. In the 1980s, the Bank realized that development projects may not succeed when the policy frameworks of governments are seriously faulty. A little later, in the 1990s, the Bank also began to realize that development policies may themselves fail if the governance structure in a country is weak and public institutions work poorly. Since the publication of its World Development Report (1997), the World Bank has proclaimed that reforming public institutions (or, the public sector) and improving governance is key to all successful development and poverty-reduction work (as the Bank’s president, James Wolfensohn, asserts in the quote above). According to the latest Bank view, good governance matters for povertyreduction as it improves the overall quality of basic social and infrastructural services while making them more accessible to the poor. During the past few decades, the World Bank has promoted good governance in developing countries by reviewing their internal accounting and audit systems, budgeting mechanisms, and rules governing the civil service and judiciary. However, during recent years, the Bank has begun to emphasize various other mechanisms which developing societies can use to facilitate reform of their public institutions, particularly in the social and infrastructure sectors. For instance, encouraging citizen (local community) participation or ‘voice’ in decision making and allowing private and public sector firms to compete in providing public services can reduce incentives for corruption and hence improve transparency and accountability in government. The World Bank has also applied the mechanisms of ‘voice’ and competition in its anti-corruption efforts, following its 1997 strategy to help developing countries fight corruption in their public institutions.5 The Bank has assisted specific countries in designing and implementing surveys of citizens, private firms, and public officials, which help strengthen the involvement of civil society in supervision of public officials and ensuring greater transparency in public decision making and service delive ry. 1 Reforming Public Institutions and Strengthening Governance: A World Bank Strategy, November 2000, The World Bank, Washington, D.C., p. 1. 2 3 See P. Kulshreshtha, (1993), ‘Governance Issues at CG Meetings: 1990–Present, An Analysis’, mimeo. Many empirical studies have confirmed that governance influences economic growth. See, for instance, P. Mauro (1995), ‘Corruption and Growth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 3, 681–712. Also, a series of cross-country studies have found empirical evidence of a strong causal relationship between better governance and better development outcomes such as D. Kaufmann, A. Kraay and P. Zoido-Lobaton (1999), ‘Governance Matters’, Policy Research Working Paper No. 2196, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. 4 For a comprehensive account, see Reforming Public Institutions and Strengthening Governance: A World Bank Strategy, November 2000, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. 5 See Helping Countries Combat Corruption: Progress at the World Bank Since 1997, June 2000. Regulatory and Contractual Framework 153 Governance concerns also affect the aid-disbursement decisions of the World Bank as well as other development agencies and bilateral donors.6 For instance, the Bank has started to incorporate governance concerns such as corruption or lack of transparency and accountability in its assessments of country or project lending risk. The Bank has also considered taking additional steps to safeguard accountability in the use of its funds by recipient governments with a poor governance record in the past. In fact, almost all Bank projects approved in recent years have a strong governance component and have attempted to reform the public institutions in the recipient country. The significance attached by the Bank to governance issues is also evident by the fact t hat about one-fourth of the Bank’s total aid-disbursement during 1997–9, which amounts to approximately $5–7 billion per annum, has been spent on institution-building efforts. 7 MIXED SUCCESS Despite increased spending on governance reform in the 1990s, the World Bank has not always succeeded in improving governance via its development projects in core areas of government as well as in specific sectors. Some important lessons that emerge from the Bank’s experience with institutional reform are as follows. Firstly, development projects that are ‘technocratic’ in nature and insensitive to the institutional realities in a developing country are less likely to succeed in strengthening governance. In particular, if the Bank does not consult with important stakeholders or groups whose support is crucial to mobilizing ideas for reform, institutional change becomes very less likely. Secondly, in the past the Bank has often depended upon models of ‘best-practice’ which may not fit all developing countries equally well. Although broad goals of good governance such as transparency, accountability, equity, and efficiency are common, the specific means that can be employed to achieve these goals may vary across countries. A deep understanding of the institutional realities of a country is essential before deciding upon the strategies and means for reform. Hence a ‘one-size-fit-all’ approach to governance and institutional development would tend to be inferior and lack effectiveness. Thirdly, weaknesses in Bank’s lending instruments and deficient staff and expertise on governance at the Bank can hamper long-term efforts to promote institutional reform. Lastly, traditional project lending and governance reforms are often in conflict with each other. This is because development projects typically target a specific action to be executed rather than attempt to change the larger institutional set-up in a developing country. Hence, achievement of project-specific objectives often comes at the expense of, and can even undermine, institutionbuilding efforts.8 However, it is important to note that in countries where governance structures are very poor, pushing project lending may be the only viable way to create and sustain economic growth. In the area of public service delivery, the Bank has also had limited success due to a variety of reasons similar to those abov e. Firstly, during the past few decades, the Bank devoted much attention to improving the capacity of public monopolies and other public organizations to deliver social and infrastructural services, rather than looking at available options for institutional reform. The mechanisms of decentralization or ‘voice’ and competition were practically ignored by the Bank for a long time, even though they were available. Secondly, the Bank has failed to avoid the trap of ‘best-practice’ models and to account for institutional complexities in the public service sector because of a poor understanding of institutional realities in this sector. 6 However, most bilateral aid-donors accept that aid-conditionality, i.e. making development assistance to a recipient conditional upon improvements in governance, can be effective only if it accords with the broad policies of the recipient country government and is agreed upon mutually. See ‘The Role of Donors and IFIs in Curbing Corruption’, Global Forum on Fighting Corruption, The Hague, 28–31 May 2001. 7 See World Bank (2000). 8 This is specifically true in projects controlled by donor countries. For instance, donors often provide salary supplements to local project employees which leads to diversion of superior skilled labour from important core areas of government. Also, availability of loans under an aid agreement can lead to lower budget discipline and distort government priorities for development across sectors. Finally, different donors may have different procedural requirements, which increases administrative burden and hampers the development of simple and efficient administrative systems in the recipient country. these examples, corruption without theft takes place when extra money is asked for issuing a ration card or a passport. Corruption with theft is a useful construct, however, only when the government has set the price of a public resource. Under such conditions, the distinction changes the marginal cost of supplying goods and services for the bribe taker. Efficiency Enhancing Corruption: The Arguments Corruption as ‘Speed Money’ or ‘Efficiency Wage’: Corruption, when the bribes are given to speed up the decisions or to cut through the red tape, is seen as efficiency enhancing by some authors. Huntington (1968: p. 386), viewing corruption as a lubricant in the wheels of bureaucracy, states: ‘In terms of economic growth, the only thing worse than a society with a rigid, over-centralised, dishonest bureaucracy is one with a rigid, over-centralized, honest bureaucracy.’ More formally, Lui (1985) models the corruption or bribery in a setting of queue formed for provision of a public service. In his model, the corrupt official is able to practise price discrimination based on 154 India Infrastructure Report 2002 the opportunity cost of the clients in the queue, and the size of the bribe is linked to this opportunity cost (bribe is decided by the bribe giver). The equilibrium strategy in his model minimizes the waiting costs associated with the queue and thereby increases efficiency in the service. Intuitively, the presence of bribe in this case acts as ‘piece rate’ paid to the official serving the queue, increasing his efficiency. Moreover, since the rate itself is paid on the basis of opportunity cost of waiting time, it allows the official to serve those clients first who put maximum value to their waiting time. Iniquitous though it may be, it thus improves welfare and allocational efficiency. Corruption as a ‘Second Best’ Solution to Policy Induced Distortions: Besides viewing the potential of corruption as a way to cut through red tape and bureaucratic inefficiency, it is also seen as ‘second best’ solution to preexisting policy induced distortions. In such cases, the state imposed distortionary policies are nullified by the corruption facilitated blackmarketing, smuggling, etc. The nullifying economic activities circumventing irrational policy and administrative decisions with the help of corruption can improve allocational efficiency and welfare, even if some resources are wasted in the process. Corruption as Efficiency Enhancing ‘Coasean Bargaining’ Process: Corruption as ‘Coasean bargaining’ process may increase efficiency by improving the welfare of an economic agent, if the public official has discretion to lower the welfare of that agent, either by imposition of penalties or denial of a public resource. The effect is stronger when the decision or action of the public official can harm the individual more than he gains from the decision. For example, if a public official, by taking a particular decision, gains Rs 100 as payoff and if the decision results in loss of Rs 200 to an individual, the individual may bribe any amount up to Rs 200 to the public official to get the decision changed. This would improve his own welfare as well as that of the public official. Corruption and Efficiency: Critique Compelling though these arguments are, the effects of corruption on efficiency are not so straightforward if the real life issues related to information asymmetry between the bribe taker and bribe giver, endogenous characteristics of red tape, lack of enforcement/secrecy associated with corruption, as well as the decentralized nature of corruption are incorporated in the analysis. Endogenous Characteristics of Red Tape and the ‘Speed Money’ and ‘Second Best’ Arguments: Myrdal (1968), quoting the 1964 Santhanam Committee Report14, argues that corrupt 14 Government of India appointed the committee for prevention of corruption. officials instead of speeding up the administrative work may increase the delays in order to maximize the bribes. Corrupt officials may create more red tape in order to screen clients in order to maximize their payoffs (Banerjee 1997). The problem is essentially due to the endogenous nature of red tape or the process as well as criteria used in allocating public resources in bureaucracies. Conceptualizing the relationship between public officials and public as that of agents (public official) engaged by the principals (public or a benevolent government), as has been done in the literature, the moral hazard [expropriation of principal(s) by the agent(s)] problems arise in the first place due to information asymmetry. In addition, the complications in this case are due to the free rider problem faced by a large number of principals, making it extremely difficult for them to write the terms of contract at which the agents are going to work for them, giving in turn considerable discretion to the agents to offer those contracts, that are in their own interest. Not only do the processes and criteria used by the public officials have the potential to be opaque, endogenous, and self-serving, the quality and quantity of public service would also be unobservable and unenforceable. Only in very special cases, such as Lui’s model discussed earlier, corruption may be efficiency enhancing. If the public officials have disutility of effort (a typical principal–agent characterization) and very weak accountability, the end result will be sub-optimal. As Andvig (1991) points out, the queues in allocation mechanisms are more complex than the queuing models used in the literature to analyse the effect of corruption in efficiency. The results on these models may not be robust to new offers of bribe made by new entrants to the queue and there is no compulsion on the part of the corrupt official to stick to the deal of maintaining priority in the queue if the information is imperfectly observable to the clients. Similar to the effect of the endogenous nature of red tape on ‘speed money’ efficiency, the policy induced distortions which corruption can ameliorate in the ‘second best’ argument are endogenous to the bureaucracies. The bureaucracy, particularly an over-centralized one (decentralized ones may find it difficult to do it as effectively owing to difficulty in co-ordinating its members), may induce such distortions in the policy framework to maximize its own payoffs. Effect of Secrecy and Lack of Enforcement Associated with Corruption: Even in the context of an economy with worst bureaucracy, corruption is illegal. Considerable inefficiency can result from the distortions created by corrupt officials to prevent detection (Shleifer and Vishny 1993). A corrupt official will induce distortions in the resource allocation to prevent detection, or to hide corruption, even if otherwise corruption is neutral to Regulatory and Contractual Framework 155 allocational efficiency. Using the example of competitive bidding of bribes for a government procurement contract under imperfect information, Beck and Maher (1986) have shown that the lowest cost firm offers the highest bribe and gets the contract. The only effect of bribery is that producer surplus is cornered by the corrupt official. However, as Shleifer and Vishny (1993) have pointed out, the corrupt official is likely to distort the procurement contract itself in a manner that competitive bidding is avoided (as it increases the possibility of detection) by altering technological, technical specifications and qualifying requirements of bidders. This may result in the creation of inappropriate and/or low quality public assets. Similarly, due to the lack of enforceability of any commitment made in a transaction involving a bribe (but for the ‘reputation’ effect, for which usually there is no incentive as it is rarely a determinant of jurisdiction given to the official), the effectiveness of corruption as a Coasean bargaining process is very weak. In the example given earlier, having realized that a decision can hurt someone more than personal gains from the decision, the corrupt official can threaten and blackmail the individual to bargain for more and more bribe, resulting in a collapse of the equilibrium. This explains why bargaining or bribing one’s way through, when the other side (say, police, tax officials) has the power to harm, is usually avoided. Only those agencies and parts of bureaucracies that have less potential to harm and can grant favours are mainly solicited for bargaining through bribes. Shleifer and Vishny have also pointed out that the type of penalties imposed on corruption also affects efficiency. If the penalty is the same on detection (does not vary with bribe), then the corrupt official will lower output (to avoid detection) and will demand a higher bribe. However, if it varies with the size of the bribe then he will increase output and lower the bribe size. An even more serious manifestation of the inefficiency of corruption takes place when corruption is decentralized and when each official acts as an independent monopolist to maximize his own payoff. For an economic activity, if multiple clearances are required, then each of the officials will act as an independent monopolist. Decentralization of corruption, in this context, simply means that multiple members of the bureaucracy act independently in the context of decision making and have independent jurisdictions. The multiplicity of decision makers and not the level of state, where the locus of decision making lies, is relevant to the concept of decentralized corruption. Extending the well-known consequence of independent monopolists, when the product demands are interdependent, Shleifer and Vishny (1993) show that the aggregate bribes asked for by such independent officials will reduce the activity as compared to when there is a single profitmaximizing corrupt official. Though decentralized bureaucracy is worse than centralized bureaucracy for efficiency, purely in terms of economic analysis, it is politically more sustainable in a fractious society (Shleifer and Vishny 1993; Mauro 1995). Summing up, it is clear that if the bureaucracy would not move otherwise and would act perversely (presumably, due to inability of principals to get their acts together), corruption may have some beneficial impact by aligning the interest of bureaucracy with public. However, when the same argument is pushed further (unaccountability of the agents and therefore, corrupt bureaucracy), it is likely that the actions and decisions of bureaucracy are more likely to be in its own interest and corruption-reinforcing, to the detriment of others. Decentralized Corruption and Efficiency: The previous arguments for and against corruption as efficiency enhancing mechanisms can be summarized by thinking of a corrupt official as a monopolist supplying goods and services or selling property rights over public resources. To the extent corruption allows him extraction of consumer (public) surplus as a discriminating monopolist, it is neutral to social welfare. As a consequence, at times it may also increase the output, thereby increasing efficiency. If the corrupt official creates more screening devices to discriminate clients and restricts output due to information asymmetry and/or secrecy (which is usually the case), corruption becomes inefficient. The presence of endogenous characteristics of the policies, rules, processes, performance evaluation, and decision making criteria within a bureaucracy with little accountability towards the public may increase the distortions even further. Besides the effect of corruption on economic efficiency, several authors have analysed and commented upon the relative size of rents (as compared to bribes) that bribery is supposed to procure for the bribe givers, the effect of corruption on dynamic efficiency (growth), factors explaining persistence of corruption and differences observed across countries, and policy issues to mitigate the incidence of corruption and its consequences. Given the nature of corruption, the empirical research is limited to a few cross-country studies, which we review later. Corruption and Economic Growth: Other Issues and Evidence Institutional Framework and Relative Size of Rents vs. Bribes: In an institutional framework, where co-ordination among corrupt officials is required in order to facilitate procurement of economic rents for bribe givers, the difficulty in co-ordination may make bribes relatively insignificant compared to the rents, a phenomenon known as ‘Tullock’s 156 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Paradox’ after Tullock (1980). In settings where no such problems exist due to the existence of a single decision maker, Krueger (1974) shows that competitive bidding by rent-seekers dissipate rent. Even in the face of co-ordination problems, the bribe takers may be able to extract higher bribes when they are well organized (Rose-Ackermann 1978). Though democracy presumably reduces the corruption by increasing the co-ordination problem for the decision makers and legislators, it may fail to eliminate rent-seeking behaviour. Institutions such as civil services clubs, disciplined party factions, etc. within a democracy, on the other hand, facilitate higher bribes for their members by reducing the co-ordination problem. Corruption and Growth Process: Dynamically, corruption can affect growth negatively as it acts as a deterrent to risk taking (Bardhan 1997). Unlike taxes which allow deduction of losses of the past against profits, the effect of bribes and corruption is asymmetrical. The growth process gets affected when the public resources are diverted from infrastructure projects, having positive externalities, to line the pockets of corrupt officials (or their private consumption). Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny (1993) show that rent-seeking activities often have increasing returns, and consequently returns to entrepreneurship and innovations often fall in comparison with the rent-seeking activities, impacting growth. Tanzi and Davoodi (1998) point out that a higher level of grand corruption is likely to bias public expenditure towards capital, as opposed to operating (revenue) expenditures, resulting in low quality of infrastructure stock. Persistence of Corruption and Differences Across Countries: In addition to cultural differences and differences in tolerance of (and even perceptions of ) corruption across societies, one major explanation offered for the relative differences in corruption across societies, is the possibility of frequencydependent multiple equilibria15 (Cadot 1987; Andvig 1991). In Andvig’s simple model, a society can easily move towards relatively corruption-free or corruption-ridden status depending on the fraction (frequency) of honest (or dishonest) officials. It pays to be honest when most of the others are honest and vice-versa. The model by Andvig and Moene (1990) shows how profitability of corruption is linked to its frequency and that a temporary shift may lead to permanent changes in corruption. An increase in the frequency of corruption lowers the cost of corruption to 15 Existence of multiple possible equilibria of honest vs. corrupt public officials. Intuitively, this means that whether it is optimal to be honest in equilibrium depends upon whether others are honest or not. A multiple of such equilibria are possible, each dependent on the frequency or proportion of honest people. The subsequent text makes this point clearer. the corrupt official (lower detection and penalty) and increases the demand for corrupt services (by reducing search costs for bribers). Tirole (1996) explains the persistence of corruption through bad collective reputation of previous generations. Younger generations inherit this reputation, eliminating the incentive to be honest. Shleifer and Vishny (1993) point out that corruption with theft is more likely to be self-reinforcing as the bribers do not have any incentive to report the corruption. Reducing Corruption: Policy Issues: Corruption arises, in the first place, due to monopoly power vested with the public official to allocate public resources. The more extensive the jurisdiction of public officials is and the more is the dependence of the private sector on public resources, the greater is the possibility of corruption. Privatization and deregulation, as Klitgaard (1988) notes, reduces the corruption in the affected jurisdictions. Multiple officials with competing and/or overlapping jurisdictions (RoseAckerman 1978,1994) reduce the monopoly power of bureaucrats and/or increase the difficulty of co-ordination. Reducing the size of government (its functions) reduces the jurisdiction of the bureaucracy. Better monitoring, accounting and disclosures (making accountability possible) can reduce the incidences of corruption with theft, which is self-preserving (Shleifer and Vishny 1993). Incentive payments to officials may also improve efficiency, particularly when accompanied by better accountability (Klitgaard 1988). The legal framework towards corruption, particularly penalties, may itself improve the incidences and consequences of corruption (Shleifer and Vishny 1993). The literature on fiscal decentralization (in the sense of moving the locus of decision making closer to the client group) has arguments both for and against its effect on lowering corruption. Wade (1997) attributes corruption in the Indian irrigation bureaucracy to its over-centralized, top–down structure. Brueckner (1999), as quoted by Fisman and Gatti (1999), however, argues that corruption is more likely in local governments. Just as a centralized bureaucracy is more likely to divert the resources to the non-poor, who are willing to pay, local governments are also vulnerable to ‘capture’ by local wealthy/powerful clients or groups (Bardhan and Mookherjee 1998), quoted by Fisman and Gatti 1999). In the context of fiscal decentralization, it has been argued that if the spending decisions are decentralized while revenue generation remains with the higher level of government, the corruption and local rent-capture may be exacerbated (Fisman and Gatti 1999). Empirical Evidence: Given the nature of corruption, there has been limited empirical research on its causes and consequences. However, anecdotes, allegations, case studies, and reports in the academic as well as popular press appear Regulatory and Contractual Framework 157 rather frequently. There are few cross-country studies that have looked at the effect of corruption on the attributes of economic performance of the cross-section. Mauro (1995) used an index compiled by Business International for 68 countries to measure the extent of corruption. Analysing cross-sectional data, he found that corruption is strongly negatively correlated with the investment rate, regardless of red tape. He concludes that corruption lowers economic growth by lowering the total and private sector investments. In addition to the Business International index, Tanzi and Davoodi (1998) used the International Country Risk Guide index, compiled by Political Risk Services, Inc., as a measure of corruption across countries. Using datasets of attributes of public expenditure across countries, they find that high corruption is positively associated with high public (capital) expenditure, low governmental revenue, high ratio of wages and salaries to total current expenditure, and poor quality of infrastructure. Fisman and Gatti (1999), using the latter index, find a negative association between decentralization and corruption. Working with the state level data, they also point out that decentralization is more effective in reducing corruption when revenue responsibility is also local (less federal transfers). To sum up, the negative effect of corruption on economic growth is widely recognized and empirically supported (albeit, in a limited sense). The institutional arrangements, extent of political decentralization (accompanied by revenue generation responsibility), privatization, deregulation, monitoring, disclosures, etc. are argued as ways to lessen the corruption or distortions caused by it. INFRASTRUCTURE SECTORS AND CORRUPTION Corruption manifests itself in the context of infrastructure by increasing the cost of infrastructure goods and services, even if they are provided by an otherwise efficient entity. This vitiates the economic, financial, and political viability of infrastructure projects in the context of economies increasingly willing to privatize infrastructure sectors. In the context of state provided infrastructure goods and services, corruption usually leads to widespread thefts, particularly when it is difficult to measure and monitor the output or when it is difficult to make officials accountable. The high incidence of theft of power or water in India are illustrative cases. Corruption also induces capital expenditure bias in decision making, thereby lowering the quality of the existing stock of assets in infrastructure sectors as fewer resources are allocated towards operating and maintenance expenditures (Tanzi and Davoodi 1998). In a similar vein, the softer infrastructure sectors (such as health and education) tend to attract lower allocations, due to fewer opportunities for corruption (Shleifer and Vishny 1993). On the other hand, infrastructure sectors involving large outlays are more susceptible to grand corruption. Even within the context of privatized infrastructure sectors, corruption by public officials can affect the private entity while framing policies and deciding on terms of entry and operation. This may include awarding of licences (if the entry is restricted), decisions related to the technology, decisions related to allocation of risks, conditionalities, and clearances required, etc. Later, the corruption may affect them through the dependence of continued operations on public officials or on the entities controlled by them, in their regulatory role or even as a buyer/seller of the output/input. Here, we focus on five main issues related to infrastructure sectors and corruption. These are: (a) decentralisation; (b) stability of policy framework and effectiveness of ‘Coasean bargaining’; (c) unbundling and corruption with theft; (d) multiplicity of independent regulators; and (e) independence of regulator/auditors. We have not discussed some of the themes such as deregulation, reducing administrative jurisdictions (size of the government), disclosures etc., which are important, but their effect on corruption in general as well in the context of infrastructure sectors is obvious. Infrastructure Projects: Decentralization and Corruption Even in the case of private provisioning of infrastructure services, the issue of decentralization is important. Centralized licensing, planning, and execution of such projects have their own pitfalls, if motivated by the private payoffs to the decision makers. The qualifying requirements and the process followed in awarding licences can be easily designed to minimize competition in bidding. Usually, enactment of such barriers also entails increasing the capital outlay requirements, as the scope of the project can be enhanced even when it is economical to unbundle it or capital-intensive technology is mandated even when other economically efficient technologies exist. The impact of these distortions, created to maximize payoffs to the decision makers, is ultimately borne by the users and economy. This is not to argue that there are no possible benefits from centralized infrastructure planning and implementation. When there are substantial economies of scale in execution and/or operation or optimal utilization of the projects, there is a good case for such centralization. However, the experiment of decentralized provisioning of primary and adult education in Madhya Pradesh shows that in certain cases (when the geographical externalities are non-existent), the locus of control at the decentralized level may result in benefits outweighing the costs of suboptimal design and execution. The effect is, however, likely to be satisfactory if the interests of stakeholders are aligned. 158 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Outside grants, if any, should be linked with the performance and revenues, so that the cost of corruption is internalized at the local level. Much of what has been said is true for even public services provided by local governments. As argued by Tiebout (1956), decentralization can induce competition as the inhabitants can vote by their feet (move out of a jurisdiction). This is true, however, only if the framework for decentralization does not permit porkbarrel politics (promise and/or delivery of ‘pork’ to the constituency by the politicians). Even in the case of centrally planned and executed projects or infrastructure services centrally provided, there is a case for giving time-bound jurisdiction to local governments for the local dimensions of the project though it may not have any effect on corruption. For example, the exact course of a road or rail location of facilities, etc. can be easily decided by the local governments, even if they cannot veto the project and/or its specifications. As we have discussed earlier, overlapping but not independent jurisdictions tend to reduce corruption. Stability of Policy Framework and Effectiveness of ‘Coasean Bargaining’ While reviewing the literature, we have seen that one of the arguments for corruption is that it allows the briber and bribee to improve their respective welfare through Coasean bargaining. The effectiveness of such bargaining, as has been argued, depends upon whether the outcomes bargained for are binding (Shleifer and Vishny 1997). In a corrupt democracy, politicians may use (or threaten to use) major or even minor changes in the policy framework to force the client (an operating entity) once again to the bargaining table. Stability of policies in the infrastructure sectors has been considered desirable as it reduces the risks for the entities and their financiers, thereby resulting in higher investments and/or lower costs. Besides the desirability of stability in policy framework from this perspective, it is also desirable as it reduces the possibility of arbitrarily high costs imposed on a private infrastructure entity. Stability in policy keeps the costs of corruption within bound in the case of a privatized but regulated sector. It is no coincidence that less corrupt countries also tend to have more stable policies and policy frameworks, and it comes as no surprise that the policy changes seem to be more frequent when the private sector is involved than when the infrastructure services are provided by the state. The costs of too frequent policy changes are low investments and high cost infrastructure. Unbundling to Reduce Corruption with Theft The economic arguments for unbundling of infrastructure services mainly come from the viewpoint of efficiency, as unbundling allows competition wherever possible, as in case of generation and distribution in power sector as opposed to vertically integrated monopolies (created because of natural monopoly, transmission (wires) business). Moreover, unbundling and pricing of services allows more effective signals for consumption as well as investments. In addition, unbundling in the context of vertically integrated businesses can also be helpful in reducing corruption with theft and better accountability. I recall my childhood memories of lay people advocating the splitting up of vertically integrated electric utility (a state electric supply board, typical of the notoriously inefficient State Electricity Boards (SEBs) not on account of economic efficiency arguments, but because it would reduce corruption. They made two arguments: (a) it will help in accounting for thefts or losses as there will be metering done between the different entities so created, and (b) it will reduce the compulsions for corruption as the jobs will be nontransferable across the entities. To elaborate the latter argument, as the maximum side payments were in distribution, everyone wanted to be posted in distribution (even the effort required on the job is less), because of which they had to pay maximum bribes for such postings. Having acquired the posting, they had to recover the same through bribes and permitted thefts. Moreover, those left out continuously tried to get such postings. The decision makers, in order to maximize payoffs over their discretion of transfer, also kept on rotating people to such postings, accentuating corruption and theft even further, simultaneously eliminating any incentive for ‘reputation building’ by the posted official. This has entrenched corruption. Though not applicable in all contexts, the arguments are still valid. Unbundling can also help by decentralizing the bureaucracy (an incentive for ‘reputation building’), by specialization of skills, and by better monitoring (mutually reinforcing arguments)16. Multiplicity of Independent Regulators Unlike the producer or seller of infrastructure services, when jurisdiction of public official is to act as a specialist regulator of the firm engaged in providing services, specialization gives rise to decentralized corruption, as pointed out earlier. Acting as independent (over their jurisdiction) monopolists, these independent multiple regulators (corrupt officials) regulating a firm can choke off investments more than a single corrupt regulator. Multiple clearances required for infrastructure projects increase administrative costs as well as potential costs of corruption. The accountability suffers due to diffusion of responsibility 16 The most challenging unbundling of all would be that of the bureaucracy [Ed.]. Regulatory and Contractual Framework 159 and efficiency suffers due to inadequate treatment of externalities. Ideally, regulatory jurisdictions over infrastructure projects, as the analysis suggests, should be combined and vested with a single regulator with a well-defined domain. Specialization, if required, should be developed or outsourced by the regulator. In the Indian context, the power sector suffers from similar problems as it is in Concurrent list of the Constitution. For any private sector player, the state government matters more, and hence the state bureaucracy has to be satisfied. The central government/national initiatives for specific private sector investments or reforms may therefore not yield results, unless states were to internalize the cost of being the independent monopolist regulator. Independence of Regulators Besides centralization of the regulatory function, another important element of reducing the corruption and associated costs is to have regulators who are independent in the sense that they are not part of the state and represent neither producers nor consumers (in a meaningful sense). Even in the case of an independent regulator, though the possibility and instances of ‘regulatory capture’ exists, separation from the state facilitates policy making to be more stable. This, by itself, is a desirable characteristic. Separation from the state increases the monitoring of regulator (by the State as well as by others) and makes it easier to ensure disclosures of decision, transparency of process, as well as insistence on regulatory rationale. Being independent of the state, regulators are likely to be more effectively scrutinized by the courts. The government or the state on the other hand can easily avoid this scrutiny, particularly in economic matters, by enacting or changing laws with the help of the legislature and by invoking the ‘public interest’ argument. The independence of the regulator requires a careful enabling framework, wherein the only scrutiny is by courts and not by any other part of the state. Similarly, the personnel associated with the regulator must not be a part of a civil service club, producers’ employees, or potential employees (often, ex-regulators are found in employment with producers) and the process should make co-ordination for corruption difficult. In the Indian context, all the five dimensions discussed in this paper are weak as far as governance in infrastructure projects is concerned. Multiplicity of regulators, lack of stable policies, little and irrational unbundling, inappropriate decentralization, and absence of independent regulators are institutional features that make for widespread corruption and increase associated costs. Policy makers and public debate need to address these issues if we are to improve governance in the infrastructure sectors. 6.4 ACCRUAL ACCOUNTING FOR INFRASTRUCTURE ASSETS: A REVIEW Mahendra Gujarathi • Samir K. Barua Large investments in infrastructure assets by governments are indicative of the contribution of such assets to the viability and effectiveness of governments, and of the public needs they serve. In the USA, for example, an estimated $150 billion is annually spent every year by the government for construction, improvement, and rehabilitation of physical infrastructure assets such as roads, bridges, dams, tunnels, water, and sewerage systems. Yet, until recently, little attention had been given in the governmental financial statements to the valuation, the measurement of depreciation, and the disclosure of the condition of infrastructure assets. As a result, financial reporting practices for infrastructure assets have been diverse and there is currently no consensus on an accounting technique for infrastructure assets (Rowles 1991). There have been sporadic attempts to deal with the issues associated with financial reporting for infrastructure assets. Standard setters in several countries, including the UK, Australia, and New Zealand, have recently issued pronouncements on accounting for infrastructure assets to address the problem of widely diverse financial reporting practices by the state and local governments (SLGs). The Canadian Institute of Chartered Accountants (CICA) has launched a study on how to account for infrastructure in public sector financial statements. Even a small country such as Mongolia has introduced a draft legislation requiring government accounting to be done on an accrual basis. While the public sector reforms have a longer history in these countries than in the US, the 1999 issuance of Governmental Accounting Standards Board Statement No. 34 (GASB 34) in the US has attracted world attention to the issue of infrastructure accounting. GASB 34 has been dubbed as the most significant change in the history of governmental financial reporting. It reflects a significant departure from the budgetary compliance type of financial reporting to one that uses economic and business criteria for reporting the operations and financial condition of local and state governments. Its departure from the budgetary compliance type of financial reporting to accrual accounting has been quite controversial. 160 India Infrastructure Report 2002 In most countries in the world, accounting standards for public sector entities in general, and infrastructure assets in particular, have either not been developed or are in the very early stages of development. The International Federation of Accountants (IFAC) has initiated a project to set accounting standards for governments. A core set of accounting standards for governments—called International Public Sector Accounting Standards (IPSASs)—have been issued by IFAC. South Africa is the first country that formally announced in August 2001 that it intended to use the IPSASs for development of public sector Generally Recognized Accounting Practice for its national government. Ian Ball, the ex-Chair of the Public Sector Committee of IFAC, was quoted in the Chartered Accountants Journal of New Zealand (June 2000) that IPSASs will gain authority because (a) IFAC has a significant international reputation and (b) as countries recognize the improvements in the quality of reporting, they will incorporate such standards in their local laws. However, there are others who believe that GASB 34 and IPSASs represent an artificial implantation of business reporting standards on the governmental sector, and hence holds little promise of enhancing decision usefulness of governmental financial statements. Whether the costs of implementing such standards are worth the expected benefits is another important concern expressed. This paper summarizes the developments in infrastructure accounting internationally (using the GASB 34 as an example), critically examines the theoretical soundness and practical difficulties in implementing the current standards, and conjectures about the prospects of adoption of accrualbased infrastructure accounting by governmental entities, particularly in the developing countries. The exposition in the paper would be of interest to the countries considering issuance of infrastructure accounting standards, or adoption of the IPSASs into their local laws. ACCOUNTING STANDARDS FOR INFRASTRUCTURE Prior to the issuance of GASB 34, SLGs had the option of reporting infrastructure assets in any fashion as long as it was consistently done and disclosed. This was perhaps the result of a judgment by the standard setters that the costs of establishing and maintaining cost records for such assets might exceed the benefits from such data. State and local governments in most of the countries currently report expenditures on infrastructure assets in the year incurred. Therefore, infrastructure assets do not appear in the statement of financial position on a continuing basis. Such accounting is consistent with the position of some authors (Mautz 1981, 1988, for example) who argued that infrastructure investments do not conform to the traditional definitions of assets. However, the view that infrastructure expenditures indeed constitute assets is gaining increasing support in the US and elsewhere. The Public Sector Committee of the IFAC concluded that it is now generally accepted that infrastructure expenditures represent assets. GASB 34 also requires the use of full accrual accounting for all government activities and the reporting of the value of infrastructure assets in the balance sheet. GASB 34 concluded that infrastructure asset reporting was ‘essential to provide information for assessing financial position and changes in financial position, and for reporting the cost of programs and functions’. GASB 34 requires all the infrastructure assets acquired, renovated, restored, or improved after the effective date of GASB 34 to be reported in the statement of financial position. The requirements of GASB 34 come into effect from the fiscal year 2002 for large SLGs (with annual revenues of $100 million or more), 2003 for medium SLGs (revenues between $10 million to $100 million), and 2004 for small SLGs (revenues less than $10 million). Additionally, significant infrastructure assets that have been acquired or significantly reconstructed since 1981are also required to be reported in the statement of financial position by the large and medium SLGs although they would have additional four years for such retroactive reporting. As per GASB 34, the amount at which infrastructure assets should be reported is the historical cost. Historical costs represent the total cost, inclusive of capitalized interest and ancillary charges incurred to put the asset into its intended location and condition for use. However, since most of the infrastructure assets were constructed under the cash accounting regime, historical costs are usually not available. In such cases, therefore, the historical costs are to be estimated by calculating the current replacement value for a similar asset, and deflating the same by applying price-level indices to the year of acquisition. After initial capitalization, infrastructure assets are to be depreciated by allocating their net cost (that is, cost less the salvage value) over the estimated useful lives in a systematic and rational manner. The depreciation expense must be recorded, allocated to functions, and reported in the statement of activities of SLGs. Any established method of depreciation is acceptable and composite methods can be used when depreciating groups of assets with different service lives. Several infrastructure assets, however, such as bridges and roads can be used for a very long period if properly maintained. Hoover Dam, for example, is expected to last 2000 years! Spreading the construction costs over such a long period makes the depreciation expense in each year to be immaterial. In recognition of the effect of preventive Regulatory and Contractual Framework 161 maintenance on the lengthening of the useful life of the infrastructure assets, GASB 34 allows SLGs to follow a modified approach. Under the modified approach, a governmental entity does not need to report depreciation expense for eligible infrastructure assets if (a) it manages the eligible infrastructure assets using an asset management system that possesses certain characteristics, and (b) it can document that the eligible infrastructure assets are being preserved approximately at or above a condition level set by the government. The entity must perform condition assessments every three years. In addition, it must provide annual information about the estimated amount needed to maintain the established condition level and the amounts actually incurred for the past five years. The modified approach resembles the method known as ‘renewals accounting’ in other countries such as New Zealand. Walker et al. (2000) define it as a ‘method of accounting for fixed assets that are intended to be maintained indefinitely whereby depreciation charges are replaced with charges in an amount that provides an allowance for renewals equal to the present value of the renewal expenditure needed over a reasonable planning period to bring the fixed assets up to a defined standard of service and repair to maintain them at that standard’. Renewals accounting is accepted in some, but not all, jurisdictions for external financial reporting. In New Zealand, for example, where accounting standards for infrastructure is in existence for over a decade, the renewal accounting method permitted by GASB 34 is not acceptable. The Steering Committee on National Performance Monitoring of Government Trading Enterprises in New Zealand rejected renewals accounting, asserting that ‘it does not result in the provision of information that is relevant to the assessment of GTE performance and financial position’. The N.S.W. Local Government Asset Accounting Manual rejected renewals accounting as an acceptable alternative to depreciation method arguing that the service potential for most assets is, for practical purposes, used up or lost and thus has to be replaced (Walker et al. 2000). RATIONALE AND SOUNDNESS PROVISIONS OF THE GASB 34 The reporting requirements of GASB 34 are intended to improve the accountability for public investments in infrastructure by enabling the users to determine whether current year revenues were sufficient to cover the cost of current year services, and to determine whether the government’s financial position improved or deteriorated as a result of the year’s operations. This will enable investors and bond rating agencies to assess the governments’ ability to repay their debts and support their service obligations. Another benefit relates to the intergenerational equity. Most of the infrastructure projects are funded through loan finance. However, the projects last for a long time after the loan is repaid. If the costs of infrastructure investments are to be borne by the generations benefiting from them, it is necessary to take into account whole-of-life expenditure on asset maintenance, not just the amount of loan instalments paid. Yet another advantage of reporting infrastructure assets is that it will provide a basis for securitization of these assets (Dornan 2000). The identification and valuation requirements of GASB 34 will enable SLGs to securitize their infrastructure assets for issuing bonds to pay for the costs of implementing asset management systems, and rehabilitating infrastructure assets. ACCRUAL ACCOUNTING: A SQUARE PEG ROUND HOLE? IN A Application of accrual accounting for infrastructure assets of SLGs appears deceptively logical at the outset because of the accounting practices followed for such assets by the business sector. However, there is a fundamental difference between private property owned by business entities and community assets owned by SLGs. In the case of private property, the owner has the right to exclude others from use except in return for value received. In the case of community property, each individual in the community has a right not to be excluded, and the SLG has a duty to make the asset available and accessible to the public. Therefore, as noted by Sunder (1999), there are legitimate economic reasons to expect that the control systems that work effectively in private-good organizations will not necessarily function well in public-good organizations. Internationally, infrastructure accounting for governmental entities is largely based on the experience of private sector entities with such accounting. The International Public Sector Accounting Standards (IPSASs) are an adaptation of the standards issued for the private sector by the International Accounting Standards Committee (IASC). The preface to the IPSASs makes this clear: ‘As most IPSASs are based on IASs, the IASC’s Framework for the Preparation and Presentation of Financial Statements is a relevant reference for the users of IPSASs’. However, Pallot (1997) surveyed the characteristics of public sector infrastructure and concluded that the nature of most infrastructure lies outside the private sector experience. The concept of depreciation on infrastructure assets is of limited relevance for SLGs. Sunder (1999) noted that depreciation serves three important purposes for business organizations. First, it helps estimate the full cost of production that can be used for pricing decisions. Secondly, 162 India Infrastructure Report 2002 it helps compute the residual surplus (that is, net income) by providing an opportunity cost of the services provided by fixed assets. Finally, it is an important inducement device for the managers to make production–investment decisions that are in alignment with the interests of the stockholders. Since managerial compensation is directly or indirectly (through stock options) dependent on net income, the managers would not invest too much in assets because the depreciation thereof would reduce the net income, and they would not invest too little either because of its likely adverse effect on revenue generation. None of the reasons above apply to governmental organizations. Inclusion of depreciation (and other fixed costs) to arrive at full cost can result in sub-optimal production decisions, especially in the short run. Secondly, computation of full costs has limited utility for SLGs because many public goods are not sold to customers at a price. In fact, in the case of SLGs, productive activity is intended to provide a service that will either be given free or intentionally offered at a price below the cost. Even for the priced services of the SLGs, allocation of depreciation costs to different services or departments is difficult. Thirdly, there is no residual claimant (stockholder) in such organizations, and therefore computation of residual surplus serves little purpose, if any. Indeed, as noted in GASB 1, ‘the governmental fund measurement focus is on determination of financial position rather than upon net income determination’. Finally, governing bodies, not the hired managers, make the investment decisions in the governmental organizations. The emphasis on accountability and stewardship role played by governmental officials is in diametric contrast to private sector entities where stockholders elect a board of directors to monitor operating and financial activities. To preserve the operating capability of governmental entities and to help them make sound pricing and production decisions, depreciation needs to be recorded using the current replacement costs of infrastructure assets, not their historical costs. The determination of replacement costs for SLGs is problematic. Many of the assets held by local and state governments are either unique, or the organization has such a dominant position in the market that its actions largely determine the exchange value of the asset. In either case, no meaningful valuation can be placed on these assets. The reliability of such valuations would be questionable and the cost, complexity, and effort involved in obtaining and reporting them would be very high. This leaves only two economic purposes of calculating and reporting depreciation in the governmental sector: computing the full cost of the governmental sector and facilitating production decisions of the public sector managers. Let us examine these further. Pricing and production decisions based on historical costs—which, in the case of infrastructure assets, could be several decades or even centuries old—can only be expected to be uneconomic. The use of historical costs frustrates the objective of preserving the operating capability of governmental entities. Preparer Difficulties in Implementing Accrual Accounting for Infrastructure The recordkeeping involved in applying traditional fixed asset accounting and reporting to infrastructure assets is deemed formidable by many governments. Determination of their replacement costs, which will serve some economic purposes, is problematic and unreliable, as noted above. The replacement cost valuation does not justify the cost, complexity, and effort involved in determining the replacement costs. Taking the inventory of assets and their initial valuation could be a challenge. GASB 34 responded to this concern by allowing an extended adoption window. All governments have a minimum of two years to adopt GASB 34, and smaller governments have been given two more years to begin following the provisions of the statement. Also, SLGs have four additional years for reporting existing infrastructure assets (acquired since 1981) and SLGs are exempted from such retroactive reporting. Only those assets acquired or constructed after the implementation date would need to follow the provisions of GASB 34 for such governments. For infrastructure built under a cooperative agreement with another government (foe example, regional authority or two-state authority), the allocation to each government is likely to be complex and contentious. The prospects of securitization might appear appealing to SLGs at the outset. However, many of the existing infrastructure assets—those acquired before 1981—are not required to be reported in the statement of financial position and hence would not provide the securitization benefit. Even for the assets reported in the financial statements of SLGs, one needs to note that most infrastructure assets are very large, indivisible, heterogeneous, and difficult to transfer. Finally, the historical cost of such assets presented in the financial statements will be of little use in deciding the market price of the securities represented by such assets. User Benefits from Accrual Accounting While the accrual accounting for infrastructure might be beneficial to the creditors and bond rating agencies, its utility for other users appears quite limited. Whether SLG will indeed make a transition to accrual accounting is uncertain. There is no enforcing authority Regulatory and Contractual Framework 163 for the GASB standards analogous to SEC (Securities Exchange Commission) for the FASB (Financial Accounting Standards Board) standards. Therefore, compliance with GASB 34 or with IPSASs is voluntary. Previous attempts to make financial reporting of SLGs more akin to that of private sector businesses have not yielded much success in the US. GASB 11 that addressed measurement focus and basis of accounting for governmental financial statements was indefinitely postponed by the issuance of GASB 17. As a result, no government implemented GASB 11 and the GASB reopened its financial reporting project that culminated in GASB 34. Governments are only required to capitalize infrastructure assets acquired—or on which significant costs were incurred—since 1981. Only the major infrastructure fixed assets are required to be capitalized retroactively. And they have two more years to do it. Depending on when the entities make the transition to the provisions of GASB, and the options chosen for transition, the comparability of governmental financial statements will be impaired for several years of the phase-in period. Given that historical costs are used, SLGs or citizens cannot use such data to demand rate adjustments. A Preferred Option: Additional Non-financial Disclosures Whereas switching to accrual accounting is suggested as a panacea to serve the needs of users, it is not one indeed. Appropriate and adequate accounting for state and local governmental units involves a far more complex set of interrelationships, to be reported to a more diverse set of users with a greater variety of interests and needs, than exists in business accounting and reporting (Mautz 1981). Financial statements based on accrual accounting are still limited to data that are both historical and financial. Such data is often not responsive to the decision maker who also need forward-looking and non-financial information. Experience indicates that financial data must be supplemented by non-monetary quantitative and qualitative information to aid decision-usefulness of the users. Van Daniker and Kwiatkowski (1986) noted that for eight out of the nine issues about which users seek information, engineering information was preferred ahead of other forms such as historical cost, replacement cost, budget to actual comparison, and financial plans. Such information sheds additional light on what is necessary to maintain or upgrade system functionality, identifies the potential risk of systems failure, and states the assumptions upon which these assessments are based. The condition of the infrastructure managed by the governments is a key indicator of their operational performance. Given concerns about the disruptions caused in recent years by system failure, it may be possible for descriptions of infrastructure condition to refer to the extent to which systems incorporate redundancy or other safeguards against such risks. Users of reports on infrastructure are likely to be concerned most about the physical condition of those assets, and proposed or projected cash flows associated with their use, repair, or modification as well as qualitative information concerning assumptions made about system functionality requirements. As noted by Keenan (1997), providing the information about deferred maintenance as supplementary disclosures gives a more complete picture of the government’s financial position and performance. Another important issue is to whether, and how, to report the loss, if any, in the future service potential of infrastructure assets. The dire consequences for communities of failing to maintain infrastructure adequately is an argument for providing users with information about changes in the physical condition of these assets, or about their level of deferred maintenance. Arguably, presenting the physical condition of the infrastructure assets in a user-friendly format will be a challenge to SLGs. Some heartening progress is, however, being made in this direction. While comparable and consistent methods to disclose qualitative information such as engineering details are not easy to specify, frameworks have been developed (Walker et al. 2000, for example) for presenting, in summary form, key engineering information about two of the major categories (sewerage systems and water supply) of infrastructure for SLGs. CONCLUSIONS SLGs throughout the world are wrestling with the issue of appropriate accounting and reporting of infrastructure assets. In many cases, standard setters have embraced accrual accounting for infrastructure assets as a part of the larger efforts to institute better accountability regimes and improved governance in the public sector. While such an approach appears sound at the outset, it is fraught with several conceptual weaknesses, and significant implementation difficulties for the SLGs. Whether the infrastructure is adequately maintained is not apparent from the disclosures currently provided in the governmental financial statements. Walker et al. (2000) suggest that a tally of investment in the infrastructure and of the amounts required to keep it operational would be critical for the policy makers within government to be fully informed. While infrastructure accounting for SLGs is a recent development in the US, the experience in New Zealand is instructive. A number of its councils started valuing 164 India Infrastructure Report 2002 infrastructure assets and reporting them in the statement of financial position as early as 1991. However, Pallot (1997) observes that nearly seven years later, there remains a diversity of practice in accounting for infrastructure assets. There are more questions than answers in the field of infrastructure accounting, despite the recent issuance of accounting standards. While accrual accounting appears to have significant costs and limited incremen-tal benefits, additional non-financial disclosures have the potential to enhance the usefulness to decision makers. 6.5 CRISES IN THE THE GOVERNANCE OF FINANCIAL INFRASTRUCTURE Samir K. Barua At the beginning of industrialization in the developing countries, financial markets were inadequate to meet the demands placed on them. This justified some form of government intervention. However, extensive directed credit programmes at subsidized interest rates proved an inefficient way of overcoming market failures and redistribution of income. Macroeconomic instability, combined with credit and interest rate controls, made matters worse. In July 1991, India, faced with the possibility of having to renege on its international financial commitments, had to urgently airlift 20 tonnes of gold to London to save its prestige in the global financial arena. The crisis of 1991 gave birth to the structural adjustment and economic liberalization programme of the 1990s to restore macroeconomic stability, both on the internal and the external fronts. The performance of the Indian economy since the crisis has been characterized by growth and increased levels of inflow of foreign capital. The Indian experience is yet another example of the thesis of ‘challenge-and-response’ proposed by the famous historian, Arnold Toynbee (1956), to explain the genesis and growth of civilizations. Toynbee observes that ‘a society . . . is confronted in the course of its life by a succession of problems’ and that ‘the presentation of each problem is a challenge to undergo an ordeal’. Civilizations either emerged stronger or perished depending on how successfully they responded to these challenges. Economic reforms too are invariably triggered by grave economic crises and the degree of success with which the crises are overcome determines the subsequent performance of an economy. A decade after the reforms began in India there is reasonable evidence that there have been gains from the reforms. These gains have been realized despite hiccups in the reforms process over the years due to misguided political arithmetic. Perhaps the biggest success story of reforms has been the progress made in the financial sector. This has been possible because of the creation and modernization of the financial infrastructure. Since this phrase may have various interpretations, it needs to be defined more precisely. The word infrastructure typically conjures up images of roads, bridges, ports, power plants, and dams—all large physical structures. Financial infrastructure, however, consists of intangible entities such as securities markets, foreign exchange markets, financial institutions, investment institutions, mutual funds, investment banks, commercial banks, and non-banking finance companies. In addition, it also includes the regulators in the financial sector such as the Reserve Bank of India (RBI), the Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI), and the Ministry of Finance of the Government of India. Governance of financial infrastructure, therefore, involves governance of the operations of these entities. This is the sense in which financial infrastructure has been interpreted in this paper. FINANCIAL INFRASTRUCTURE: A BRIEF REVIEW The financial infrastructure of the country was very much centralized and archaic, till the reforms began in 1991. Its governance was divided between the Reserve Bank of India and the Ministry of Finance, the former governing the banking sector, non-banking finance companies, and the debt and foreign exchange market and the latter governing the financial institutions, investment institutions, and the stock markets. The limited freedom of decision making given to the entities implied that there were no explicit penalties for inefficient utilization of infrastructure. However, the deficiencies of the insular nature of financial infrastructure were realized after the 1991 financial crisis and the 1992 securities scam. These crises led to significant additions to the financial infrastructure in the 1990s. The reforms resulted in: • Setting up of the Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI) in 1992 to oversee the operations of securities markets • Setting up of private mutual funds to channelize savings into securities markets • Setting up of a modern stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, with screen-based trading and computerized settlement system Regulatory and Contractual Framework 165 • Setting up of primary dealers and subsequent creation of a network of dealers in government securities to activate the government securities market • Setting up of a network of dealers in foreign currency • Setting up of National Securities Depository Limited (NSDL) and subsequently Central Depository for Securities Limited (CDSL) for electronic recordkeeping of holding and transfer of securities and creation of a network of depository participants • Setting up of a large number of private banks to introduce competition in the banking sector • Constitution of Disinvestment Commission and subsequently Department of Disinvestment to manage privatization of Public Sector Undertakings (PSUs) • Modernization of stock exchanges through the introduction of computerized trading and settlement system in all the major exchanges and dematerialization of securities • Expansion of network of brokers dealing in securities through use of satellite for on-line trading in stock exchanges from all parts of the country • Modernization of the settlement system for government securities through computerization of operations of the Public Debt Office (PDO) of the RBI. The creation of these and similar facilities required changes in the rules and regulations that governed operations of various segments of the financial sector. Unfortunately, the process followed for framing the right set of regulations has by and large been quite unscientific and ad hoc, with little prior application of mind. That has generally resulted in continual changes in the regulatory structure, thereby reducing the benefits derived from the infrastructure created. As would be apparent later, many issues in governance of the financial infrastructure arise from poor regulations. Some of the regulations were framed without taking into account the cost of prudential supervision required for observance of the regulations. Since penalties arising from non-observance of regulations still tend to be mild, and easily challengeable in the courts of law, there have been several instances of breach of regulations. As a result, the financial sector has witnessed several scams/crises since the onset of liberalization in 1991. Three major crises have been analysed in the paper. The analysis provides the basis for enunciating the key issues in governance of financial infrastructure and the measures required for improvement. The Three Crises The financial sector has experienced several scams/crises in the last decade. Since it would be infeasible as well as repetitive to discuss all of them, it was decided to focus attention on three scams/crises that together provide a basis for covering most of the issues in governance of the financial sector. Two of these crises occurred recently, while the third occurred almost at the beginning of the reforms process. The three scams/crises chosen for detailed analysis and discussion are the following: (i) the securities scam of 1992; (ii) the Madhavpura Mercantile Cooperative Bank (MMCB) Scam of 2001; and (iii) the US-64 crisis of 2001. The above three events are described and discussed in detail, identifying the fault lines that precipitated the events. The events are then analysed to crystallize the issues that arise from the point of view of governance of financial sector. The issues discussed are brought together for a comprehensive examination in the last section to spell out the steps required to improve governance of the financial sector in the country. THE SECURITIES SCAM OF 1992 The 1992 securities scam was in essence a diversion of funds from the banking sector, in particular from the interbank market in government securities to the stock market. The main motivation for the diversion was the significantly higher cost of finance in the stock market as compared to the cost of finance in the formal money market (the inter-bank market). While the returns in the money market at that time hovered around 18–20 per cent, the returns from financing of carry-forward positions in the stock market (that is, badla financing) were around 35–40 per cent. The difference was much higher than what could be justified on the grounds of higher risk in the informal market. The reason for the excessive returns prevailing in the badla market was the artificial segmentation of the formal and the informal money markets. The stage was therefore set for anyone who could find a way of breaching the ‘Chinese’ wall that separated the two markets and arbitrage between the two. The scam was essentially a breach of this wall. The Macro Environment It is necessary to recall the macroeconomic environment prevailing in 1991–2 to understand the setting for the scam. The process of economic liberalization had started in earnest after the jolt the nation received from the transfer of 20 tonnes of gold into the vaults of Bank of England as guarantee against urgent short term borrowing from the Bank of Japan to ward off defaulting on international financial commitments. The first task of the new government that came into power in the summer of 1991 was to strengthen the external sector. This sector therefore witnessed major reforms. The immediate fallout of the balance of payments crisis was the use of Public Sector Enterprises (PSEs), particularly the oil sector PSEs, to raise resources in the international markets. While this brought in the 166 India Infrastructure Report 2002 much-needed dollars to the country, the measure burdened the PSEs with huge interest costs arising from excess cash holding. The government therefore designed a Portfolio Management Scheme (PMS) under which the PSEs were allowed to park the excess cash with nationalized banks to earn decent returns to meet the interest costs. The banks in turn asked for and obtained relaxation in the norms for investment to deal with the sudden rise in their liquidity. The banks also started competing for these funds by offering higher returns. They therefore had to find ways of deploying the fund to earn returns higher than what they had offered to the PSEs. Such returns were not available in the formal money market where banks traditionally deploy excess cash. This is when the brokers who were operating in both the formal and the informal markets became very useful to find an innovative way of deploying funds from the formal money market to the informal money market to earn higher returns. The stock market was booming—in less than a year, from May 1991 to February 1992, the stock market index (BSE-30 or the SENSEX) had risen from a level of below 1000 to about 4500. The steep rise in the index resulted in an exponential growth in the demand for funds required for supporting the long positions in the market. Investors were willing to pay high interest rates for these short-term funds since the rise in prices of shares more than compensated the cost of funds. This cultivation of brokers by the banking sector is what finally culminated in the securities scam. The Modus Operandi The mechanism for transfer of funds from the formal to the informal market was the ready forward (RF) deal, which in essence is a secured short-term loan from one bank to another. Ready forward deals are known as repo (repurchase option) transactions in other countries. These are used by the banking sector to manage short-term liquidity. In fact, the RF deal is not a loan at all. The borrowing bank (Bank 2) sells (government) securities to the lending bank (Bank 1) while simultaneously agreeing to buy the securities back at a slightly higher price at the end of the agreed period. The difference in the buy and sale prices is the cost of short-term borrowing. The transaction essentially serves the short-term needs of both banks—while Bank 2 needs cash, Bank 1 is looking for deployment of excess cash for the period. In addition to facilitating management of cash, the RF deals provide the much-needed liquidity to the government securities markets. It is clear that if the above process is strictly followed, then the RF deals could not have been used for diversion of funds. The following modifications in the process were introduced imperceptibly to perpetrate the scam: • As the importance of brokers rose with the introduction of PMS, the settlement process in the government securities market became broker intermediated, that is, the delivery and payments started getting routed through the brokers instead of being done directly between transacting banks; • Soon after the above procedure got established, the brokers were able to persuade the banks to credit the monies routed through them to their accounts for a few days, though the account payee cheques were drawn in favour of banks; • While the above two steps just transformed the loan to the borrowing bank to loan to the intermediating broker, the loan still remained a secured loan. Very soon, however, the brokers were able to persuade the lending bank to dispense with security for the loan or to accept worthless pieces of paper as security. It would be instructive to understand why these aberrations could be introduced in the processes since they have a significant bearing on issues in governance. Banks are required to invest a significant portion of their deposits in designated securities to ensure adequate liquidity of assets. These are known as SLR (Statutory Liquidity Ratio) securities. These securities are essentially government securities that yield low returns. The regulation, however, exempted funds borrowed by a bank from SLR requirements. There was, therefore, huge incentive for a bank to do business using borrowed funds through repo transactions. In such an environment, the brokers came in handy, as they provided an opaque process, where the identity of the counter-party (a bank) was not even revealed or known. Slowly, as the size of the repo market grew, the brokers started taking positions in their own account. The process of settlement in the government securities market started resembling the process of settlement in the stock markets, where both the payment and delivery of securities are broker intermediated. Usually, an account payee cheque is deposited only in the name of the payee mentioned on the cheque. However, exceptions were being made even before the scam occurred because the system of clearing of cheques was faster for inter-bank transfers. Privileged customers were routinely allowed to credit account payee cheques drawn in favour of their banks into their own accounts to cut down the clearing time by upto two days. Therefore, corporate customers typically obtained a cheque in the name of their bankers rather than in their own names, thereby reducing the interest lost for the clearing period. The brokers were quietly accorded a similar facility by the banks, as they had in any case become major business partners of the banks. Regulatory and Contractual Framework 167 The third aberration of eliminating the security itself was the most crucial. The following three approaches were adopted to achieve this: • Some banks were persuaded to part with cash without receiving securities, with brokers paying interest at a rate higher than the rate prevailing on the RF deals. The bank management may have been tempted to adopt this route to bolster the bottomline. As long as the scam lasted, the banks benefited from higher returns on their lending. • The second route was replacing the securities with fake Bank Receipts (BRs). The BRs had come into existence in the market to avoid actual transfer and re-transfer of the securities underlying the RF deals, due to the inefficient functioning of the RBI’s Public Debt Office (PDO), that acts as the registrar and the transfer agent for government securities. Legally, the transfers required submission of Subsidiary General Ledger (SGL) forms to the PDO to effect the changes in ownership of securities. The lethargy of the PDO led to the ‘market practice’ of using BRs as evidence of transactions. The BRs could simply be torn and thrown away at the expiry of the RF deal period by the lenders, thereby eliminating the need for actual transfer and re-transfer of securities through the inefficient process. • The third route was to forge the securities themselves. The PSU bonds, typically, were represented by just the allotment letters. Outright forgery, however, accounted for only a small part of the total funds misappropriated. Of the three, use of fake BRs was the most rampant. The brokers used fake BRs, signed by colluding bankers, to obtain unsecured loans from banks. The Governance Issues The scam was made possible due a complete breakdown in the governance systems within the commercial banks as well as the RBI. The governance system in the commercial banks essentially relies on the following two mechanisms for prevention of frauds: Separation of Functions: The three different aspects of transactions in securities, namely, dealing, custody, and accounting are carried out by separate departments. Dealing involves the decision to buy and sell; custody involves receiving and delivering securities; and accounting involves maintenance of the investment accounts of the bank and reconciliation with the SGL account of the bank maintained by the PDO of the RBI. Underlying the separation of functions is the notion of double or multiple custody, which ensures that if a fraud is to be committed, two or more persons would have to collude. The need for such collusion considerably reduces the chances of frauds. Counterparty Limits: Whenever an RF deal was done on the basis of BRs, the lending bank had to contend with the possibility that the BRs might not be backed by adequate securities. In effect, the bank could therefore be giving an unsecured loan. The Banks therefore operated with credit limits (counterparty limits), based on the creditworthiness of the borrowing bank. The total exposure to the borrower, at any time, was limited to this amount. The scam revealed that either these basic principles of governance did not exist or were ignored by several banks. The governance system at the PDO required reconciliation at the aggregate level and at the disaggregated level (for each bank) of the SGL securities of each type. This simple control mechanism was not being operated efficiently by the PDO. Even if the SGL form sent by the seller bounced due to inadequate inventory of securities, the information to the buyer was intimated leisurely— through a letter sent by ordinary mail. It was not uncommon for transacting parties to receive confirmation or otherwise of the transaction from the PDO after three weeks from the date of transaction. The buyer in the meantime, acting in good faith, may have sold the securities purchased. The laid-back attitude of the PDO implied that at any point in time there would be a large volume of unreconciled transactions. This uncertainty was exploited to the hilt. The RBI is also expected to carry out on-site inspections and audit the investment accounts of banks. These were not quite comprehensive and the RBI did not act decisively against irregularities discovered either during such inspection or in the SGL accounting. Other Aspects of the Scam There were several other aspects of the scam that have a bearing on governance of financial sector. During the period from September 1991 to June 1992, the government raised the coupon rate on fresh borrowing three times. On each occasion, the rate was raised by 0.50 per cent, thereby raising the rate from 11.50 per cent to 13 per cent over the period. A hike in rate for fresh loans leads to a fall in the prices of old loans so as to bring the yields on the old loans in line with the new rate. Anyone with advance information about the rate hikes could benefit immensely by short selling long dated securities (that suffer the maximum decline in values) just before the hikes and buying them back immediately after the rate hike. While it will be impossible to prove conclusively that some players in the market had advance information on the rate hikes, there are reasons to believe that this information was selectively made available to a few players who made a killing on the basis of the information. Window dressing of banks’ financial performance was also rampant in those days. Banks were permitted to carry their investments in securities at cost. This led to the use of a subterfuge, whereby a bank could generate profits 168 India Infrastructure Report 2002 literally from thin air. The mechanism for achieving this is best conveyed through an illustration. Let us say Bank ABC holds two securities X and Y, each purchased at Rs 100. Because of a rise in the interest rates, suppose the securities are selling in the market at Rs 97 and Rs 99 respectively. The bank sells security X to a broker at Rs 102 and buys security Y from the same broker at Rs 104, receiving and paying thereby Rs 5 more than the prevailing prices. This ensures that neither the bank nor the broker incurs a loss on the two transactions taken together. As a result of the transaction, however, the bank would be able to show an accounting profit of Rs 2 on sale of security X—since X is sold at a price of Rs 102 and it was bought at a price of Rs 100. The higher price paid for security Y is inconsequential since that shows up on the books at cost. Such window dressing had become quite common. The brokers were useful as they were willing to accommodate such ‘spurious’ deals. While the broker typically did not make any money on such transactions, he put himself in the good books of the bank’s management and was in a position to extract favours from the management in variety of other ways, such as obtaining unsecured loans. MMCB SCAM Madhavpura Mercantile Co-operative Bank (MMCB) is an urban co-operative bank. Such banks are essentially local banks set up on the co-operative principles. They are expected to cater essentially to the financial needs of the members. There are over 2000 co-operative banks in the country, with a deposit base of over Rs 70,000 crores. Maharashtra and Gujarat together have more than 50 per cent of the banks in number and about 75 per cent of the deposit base, reflecting the strength of the co-operative movement in the two states. The other two states that too have a vibrant co-operative banking sector are Karnataka and Andhra. The co-operative banks are an extremely important part of the financial infrastructure of the cooperative sector in the country. Mechanics of the Scam The MMCB scam is yet another instance of diversion of funds from the banking sector to the stock market à la the securities scam of 1992. MMCB started financing the stock market operations of Ketan Parekh, the latest (now fallen) Big Bull of the Indian stock markets. The modus operandi of financing Ketan Parekh was through a simple subterfuge that is best understood through the following illustration. You open one current account in the name of company P in bank A and another current account in the name of company Q in bank B. Now, present a pay-order (issued by bank A) of company P to bank B and have it purchased by bank B and credited instantly to the account of company Q. It takes a few days—and the period can be lengthened, if required, by greasing the palms of the concerned officials in the bank—before the pay-order is presented by bank B to bank A. You keep track and on the day of presentation, you present a pay-order (issued by bank B) of company Q to bank A and have it immediately purchased by bank A. The cycle can be repeated again and again, and you would enjoy few days’ credit every time. All you need is accommodation from bank A to write the first pay-order for you without adequate or any balance in the account of company P. You write cheques against the money provided by bank B when it purchases the pay-order from bank A. Neither of the banks actually loses out since you would be paying them the fee for discounting the pay-orders and giving you immediate credit. However, a fraud is committed when the pay-order is issued by bank A, without adequate balance. Bank B has merely been imprudent in allowing cheques to be issued without first collecting the amount against the pay-order purchased from bank A. However, bank B, may be excused if you happen to be Ketan Parekh, the demi-god of stock markets, who has been a good client of the bank for years! A pay-order of a mere Rs 137 crores is a pittance, given the scale of his operations. Banking after all is business based on relationship and trust carefully built over a long period. The Need for the Scam The settlement procedure at the stock exchanges needs to be understood to appreciate the raison d’être for the above set of transactions. The stock exchanges have what are known as pay-in and pay-out dates for each settlement cycle. The pay-in date precedes the pay-out date by two days. On the pay-in day, the buyer has to make the payment for the purchases made and on the pay-out date the sellers receive the monies due to them. An operator therefore needs working capital, for two days, even if the aggregate monetary value of his sales is greater than the aggregate value of his purchases. Using the above method, what Ketan Parekh did was to generate this working capital required for his market operations. However, he needed two banks to do the subterfuge—MMCB (which would be bank A in the example above) that was willing to commit the fraud and Bank of India (which would be bank B in the example) that was willing to be lenient and had the requisite resources to fund his requirements. The Governance Failure The issue that has exercised the passions of lakhs of depositors is the monumental negligence on the part of the Regulatory and Contractual Framework 169 regulators of co-operative banks—the State and the Central Registrar of Co-operatives and the RBI. Each regulator successfully got out of trouble by blaming the scam on the ‘dual control’ of the co-operative banks. A closer examination however reveals that signs of wrongdoings were available to both the regulators well before the scam of such magnitude came to light. In its inspection report of 1998, the RBI had pointed out irregularities in the management of operations of MMCB. And yet, because of the political patronage enjoyed by the management of the bank, no corrective action was initiated by either of the regulators, each secure in the knowledge that in case of an eventual fraud, they would be able to get away by blaming it on ‘dual control’! There is little doubt that the scam was the outcome of negligent and perhaps deliberate regulatory bungling. After all, which agency would like to take up cudgels against the might of political interference? US-64 CRISIS As the name makes it amply clear, Unit Scheme-64 (US64) was created in 1964. The scheme was conceived by the government to mobilize savings from the household sector for the industrial sector of the economy. The management of the scheme was entrusted to the Unit Trust of India (UTI), an autonomous investment institution created through an act of parliament. Over the years, UTI became a well-respected and important part of the financial infrastructure of the country. Though UTI created several schemes subsequently for the purpose of channelizing savings, no scheme even came close to the level of success that was achieved by US-64. The scheme, and through it UTI itself, became synonymous with how public institutions can successfully serve the needs of millions of Indians— in this case, by providing decent returns on their hard earned savings. Absence of Supervision The high profile of UTI was used by the management of UTI to successfully counter the repeated attempts by the Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI), to bring UTI under the purview of its supervision. SEBI was established in 1992 to supervise the functioning of stock exchanges and the associated intermediaries, including mutual funds. Though UTI essentially functions as a mutual fund, it took refuge in the fact that it was created well before SEBI was established and that it was created through an Act of Parliament to stay out of the clutches of SEBI. Operating Policies and Crisis Since UTI is not covered by the regulations that govern the mutual fund industry, it is not bound by the disclosure requirements of the industry. As a result, even today, the Net Asset Value (NAV) (the market value of the assets) of the units of US-64 is not known with certainty. One of the key reasons for the success of US-64 has been the liquidity of the units. Till the imposition of the ban (from 2 July 2001), UTI provided continuous two-way quotes, for sale and repurchase of units, without any restriction on the number of units tendered or demanded. The sale and repurchase prices were revised every month, essentially to account for the dividend payable on the units in July every year. Since the scheme was outside the purview of mutual fund regulations, UTI was free to set the sale and repurchase prices of units at levels that were unrelated to the NAV. This unscientific pricing policy is what led to the crisis facing the scheme today (August 2001). The easiest way to understand the crisis is through a simple illustration. Let us assume that US-64 has a corpus of just 2 units of Rs 10 each. One unit is held by Mr A and the other unit by Mr B. The repurchase and sale prices for each unit are say Rs 13 and Rs 13.25, respectively. Now suppose, Mr B sells his unit to UTI at Rs 13, then the corpus of the scheme would decline to Rs 7. After that, if Mr A too tenders his unit, then UTI would have no money to repurchase his unit at the declared price of Rs 13, since the fund available would be only Rs 7. Every repurchase at inflated prices thus adds to the losses of those who remain invested in the scheme. The losses do not occur only if the number of units sold exceeds the number of units repurchased. The ongoing crisis was triggered by the decline in the value of equities after the discovery of the scam involving the MMCB (Madhavpura Mercantile Cooperative Bank) and other banks. As a result of the decline in equity prices, the NAV of US-64 declined well below the repurchase price. This generated an intense redemption pressure on the scheme, and every repurchase at a price well above the NAV compromised the financial viability of the scheme further. Unable to stop the avalanche of redemptions, the UTI Board announced, in June 2001, suspension of repurchase and sale of units for an indefinite period. The ban affected an estimated 20 million retail investors as the liquidity of their investments disappeared overnight. The nationwide uproar found an echo in the Parliament where the proceedings of the house were held up for several days on the issue. There were allegations galore of how the interests of investors had been compromised by UTI because of political and bureaucratic influences on its investment decisions. One of the celebrated cases that resulted in the forced resignation of the chairman and two executive directors of UTI, and start of an investigation by the Central Bureau of Investigations (CBI), is the investment 170 India Infrastructure Report 2002 made by UTI in the equity of Cyberspace Limited. The head-office of this company is located at Lucknow and was allegedly inaugurated by the prime minister himself. The finance minister categorically denied having any knowledge of the impending crisis and the precipitate decision of the board. A new chairman was appointed hastily and the UTI board was directed by the government to work out a mechanism to ensure liquidity of US-64. Response to the Crisis After considerable deliberations, the UTI board proposed a scheme, whereby, beginning 1 August 2001, UTI would provide the facility of repurchase of upto 3000 units of US-64 from each folder. Starting with Rs 10 for the month of August 2001, the repurchase price for a unit would increase by 10 paise every month, till it reaches Rs 12 by May 2003. In addition, the UTI board has decided to make US-64 NAV based scheme, that is, align the repurchase and sale prices with the NAV, from January 2002. The seriousness of the situation is evident from the line of credit for about Rs 3000 crores that UTI had to seek from a consortium of banks (led by the State Bank of India) to meet the likely redemption pressure on US-64 and pay dividends on its other schemes. The proposal is a recipe for bankrupting the US-64 even further. Since the current NAV of the units is well below Rs 10 (market’s assessment is that the NAV is about Rs 8.50), every unit purchased at the announced prices would result in erosion in the corpus of the fund (as explained in the illustration). The proposal would thus inflict heavy losses on the hapless unit-holders who are ‘forced’ to stay with the scheme since they hold more than 3000 units. The proposal sets US-64 on the path to certain doom and bankruptcy since under the prevailing situation there is unlikely to be any fresh inflows into the scheme. The limitations of the proposal are as follows: • It robs Peter (the unit-holders who are forced to stay invested in the scheme) to pay Paul (the exiting unitholders). • It is unfair to 20 million retail unit-holders vis-à-vis the corporate unit-holders who exited in the nick of time— just before the ban was imposed on repurchases—because of (alleged) access to inside information. • Even if legally UTI is well within its rights to revise the repurchase price downwards by over 30 per cent overnight, the move is morally bankrupt. • The lock-in forced on units beyond 3000 in each folder violates the understanding conveyed over 36 years— that UTI would always stand ready to repurchase the units. • The insurance companies that are bailing out UTI by buying large parcels of equity portfolio of US-64 are engaged in ‘cherry picking’, that is, picking up the best stocks, thereby leaving the portfolio of US-64 poorer in quality. Since repurchase prices would continue to be above the NAV, every repurchase would bleed the scheme (there would be cash-outflow from the corpus). The saying ‘those who do not learn from history are condemned to repeat it’ is applicable to the crisis facing UTI today. The crisis of 2001 is a repeat of the crisis that occurred in 1998 when the NAV of US-64 units declined well below the repurchase and sale prices of units. On that occasion, the government bailed out UTI through an infusion of Rs 3300 crores. It is evident that UTI did not learn from that experience and the problem has recurred. Looking back, UTI failed to use an excellent opportunity to completely restructure the portfolio of US-64 and make the sale and repurchase prices of the scheme NAV based when the SENSEX crossed the 6000 mark in February 2000. Aligning the repurchase and sale prices now with NAV would be blatantly unfair to the millions of small investors who have been loyal to the scheme and bought the units at prices well above the NAV. The solution possibly lies in the government coming to the rescue of the trust yet again. The Larger Concerns In the prevailing circumstances, there is a distinct possibility of a psychological backlash from investors. Any hint of further unfavourable developments for the economy or UTI could trigger a run on UTI for redemption. Besides, since it is clear that some time or the other in the near future, UTI will have to liquidate its equity portfolio, to pay interest, and repay the funds being provided by the banks, there would be selling pressure in the market at every rise. The equity markets would, therefore, stay depressed. It would, therefore, be hardly surprising if the first NAV that is announced by UTI in early 2002 (as promised by the Board) turns out to be quite low—say Rs 5 per unit. Such an announcement would most certainly knock the bottom out of the equity markets. Thus the equity market today is on a precipice—in an unstable equilibrium. The slightest hint of trouble would send it tumbling downhill. The country cannot afford such a situation. The uncertainty could lead to a sudden, massive withdrawal of funds by foreign institutional investors (FIIs). It would also have a significant negative impact on the ambitious programme of divesting government’s stakes in PSEs and the ability of firms to raise resources from the market. The government should be seriously concerned about these possibilities and take steps to avoid such eventualities. Governance Issues The crisis raises several concerns about the manner in which public financial and investment institutions that are key constituents of the financial sector are managed in the Regulatory and Contractual Framework 171 country. The incestuous relationship between the corporate sector and these institutions raises suspicions about the quality of decisionmaking and corporate governance in these institutions. For example, in the case of UTI, while Reliance had invested several hundred crores in the units of US-64, the UTI had ‘obliged’ by buying large quantities of shares of the Reliance group companies. As reported in the press, these shares have typically accounted for over 15 per cent of the equity portfolio of US-64 scheme. Such quid pro quo was evident when UTI acquired a large parcel of Reliance shares (worth about Rs 1000 crores) some years ago at a very high price. Given such close liaison between UTI and the large corporations, there is little reason not to suspect that at least some corporations may have been quietly tipped off about the impending suspension of redemption. They exited before it was too late, leaving the 20 million retail investors to take the losses arising from mismanagement of the scheme! The forced resignation of the top management of UTI for purchase of shares of a small, unknown company, Cyberspace Limited, at inflated prices is a clear pointer to the fact that many of the investment decisions made were not in the interests of the unit-holders. The absence of denial by the government lends credence to the allegation that the head-office of Cyberspace, located at Lucknow, was inaugurated by the Prime Minister. There are also persistent allegations, that have again not been denied unequivocally by the government, that shares of many companies have been purchased by UTI due to political pressures and interference from officials from the Ministry of Finance and even the PMO (Prime Minister’s Office). These are clear evidences of exceptionally poor corporate governance practices in the management of the financial sector in the country. It is amazing how the institutions never have to pay any price in India for such clear breach of trust or down right skullduggery. Removal of Mr Subramanyam, Chairman of UTI, is hardly an adequate response to the fiasco. There is a need for honest investigation to unearth the role played by bureaucrats and politicians in the utter mismanagement of funds entrusted to UTI by the common man. The fiasco has after all affected 8–10 per cent of the country’s population. There is an urgent need for complete restructuring of the framework for governance of the financial sector in the country. The opportunity should be used by the nation to demand a thorough professionalization of the functioning of not only UTI but all publicly funded financial institutions. LESSONS FROM THE SCAMS It is quite clear from the exposition in the preceding sections that the scams/crises were the result of both erroneous operating policies as well as ineffective governance structures. The broader issue is whether the right lessons were learnt from these and whether measures were initiated to revamp the operations and the governance of the financial infrastructure to ensure its effective functioning. Market Integration One of the most important lessons from the scam of 1992 is that artificial insulation of closely related markets from each other is counterproductive in the long run. Money always seeks out the highest possible return, after due adjustment for risks and liquidity. However, even almost a decade after the scam, artificial barriers still exist between the money market and the stock markets, between the market for corporate securities and the market for government securities, and between the formal and the informal money markets. As a result, the market infrastructure remains ineffective in guiding investment choices and there are still pay-offs if funds could be surreptitiously diverted from one market to another. It was hardly surprising, therefore, that the MMCB scam occurred in 2001, again involving diversion of funds from the banking sector to the stock market. The fiat issued by RBI to commercial banks to reduce their exposure to equity markets after the MMCB scam is a retrograde step as it accentuates the segmentation of markets. The need of the hour is more effective prudential supervision and not a ban on legitimate financial activity. Over-regulation Analysis reveals that very often scams/crises result from over-regulation. The regulations of the money market in 1992 were such that legitimate and essential transactions could not be put through openly, but had to be disguised and camouflaged. The role of the brokers and some of the banks as market makers was not recognized and they could perform these functions only by subterfuge. The payment and clearance systems were so antiquated that ‘alternate systems’ had to be created for speedy transfer of funds and securities. The net result of all these was total lack of transparency in the operations of the money market. Irregularities of all kinds were so common that no suspicions were aroused even by highly irregular transactions. One could even argue that some of the control systems in the banks broke down because they were deliberately allowed to weaken by both the commercial banks and the RBI so as to facilitate normal transactions in violation of the RBI’s own guidelines. While several steps have been taken by the government to reduce the regulatory burden of the market, the money markets continue to be excessively regulated by the RBI. 172 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Dual/Multiple Control The old adage ‘everyone’s responsibility is nobody’s responsibility’ is what resulted in the MMCB scam. The urban cooperative banks are currently regulated by three authorities: the central government, the state governments (through the central and state registrars of cooperatives), and the RBI. Instead of strengthening governance, such multiplicity of regulators for an entity in fact undermines prudential supervision. That is exactly what happened in the case of MMCB. Each regulator expected the other regulators to keep an eye on the operations of the bank. The irony is that, if reports appearing in the newspapers are to be believed, the RBI is planning to propose the creation of a fourth regulator, an apex supervisory body, consisting of representatives from the central and the state governments, the RBI itself, and outside experts, for governance of cooperative banks. It is obvious that either we do not learn from our mistakes or such governance structures are deliberately created so that the regulators can explain away lapses in supervision by blaming each other when the scams do occur. Integrated Prudential Supervision By their very nature, financial markets are highly interrelated. Crisis in one market, therefore, always creates ripples of disturbances in the other markets. If different regulators have jurisdiction over different markets, then it is necessary for the regulators to evolve a well-coordinated regulatory structure for effective prudential supervision. In India, at least four regulators—RBI, SEBI, DCA (Department of Companies Affairs), and the Ministry of Finance—govern different aspects of functioning of financial markets. The financial crises that have occurred in India in the last decade, including the three discussed in this paper, clearly show that the required degree of harmony among regulators for effective supervision has not been achieved. There is also a simmering turf war between the regulators, particularly between SEBI and RBI. This has immensely harmed the functioning and development of the financial market infrastructure in the country. There is an urgent need for improvement in the governance structure either through better co-ordination or through a unification of regulation under one super-regulator. several other roles. It is banker to the central and state governments, it is merchant banker to the governments— helping governments to raise resources from the market, it is a major player (operator) in both the primary and the secondary debt markets and the foreign exchange market, and it is the custodian, registrar, and transfer agent for government securities. It is a promoter of and a major shareholder in several entities in the financial sector. For example, it recently promoted Infrastructure Development Financial Company (IDFC) to give a boost to development of infrastructure in the country. It holds majority stakes in the largest commercial bank in the country, the State Bank of India (SBI) and National Housing Bank (NHB—another institution promoted by RBI). The multiplicity of roles and responsibilities dilutes the efficacy with which RBI can play the role of an impartial regulator and adjudicator of disputes. The partiality shown by RBI to NHB and SBI while investigating the 1992 scam drew considerable criticism and undermined its authority as a regulator. A similar approach to dealing with the MMCB crisis is also visible in 2001. A regulator commands moral authority over the regulated only if it is not only fair but is also perceived to be fair. Therefore, for effective governance a regulator must shed all roles that have the potential for creating a conflict of interest while performing its regulatory function. Regulators on the Boards of the Regulated Both SEBI and RBI have nominees on the governing boards of stock exchanges. The RBI has its nominees on the governing boards of commercial banks, primary dealers, and several other entities in the financial markets. Their presence in the governing boards creates a strange situation when these entities are found to have acted in violation of the prevailing regulations. The regulators themselves become morally responsible for the violations of the regulations since they have their representatives on the boards of these entities. In the present day and age, it should be easily possible to use appropriate statistical analysis along with information and communication technologies to monitor the operations of the regulated entities, from regulatory perspective, on a real time basis, if required, without representation on the boards of the regulated entities. Multiple Role for the Regulator Government’s Response The Reserve Bank of India is one of the two major regulators of financial infrastructure in India. It has jurisdiction over a diverse set of facilities such as commercial banks, nonbanking finance companies, cooperative banks, debt markets, foreign exchange markets, and several other financial institutions. In addition to being a regulator, RBI plays The ultimate responsibility for proper functioning of the financial sector in the country rests with the government. It is, therefore, necessary to examine the role played by the government in establishing credible governance structures. An analysis of government’s response shows that the government has invariably panicked when faced Regulatory and Contractual Framework 173 Box 6.5.1 SEBI Report: A Damp Squib It took SEBI over six long months to finalize its second ‘interim’ report on the securities scam of 2001. The report runs into (as per the press) impressive four volumes and 1500 pages. As of now, the report is not available in the public domain. However, excerpts from the report have been released selectively to counter the bad publicity SEBI has been receiving from the conclusion reached by a survey conducted by FICCI that investors have lost confidence in SEBI. The report makes little progress over the first interim report that was brought out soon after the crisis struck the markets in early March. It simply reconfirms what is already known. The three distinct strategies that were being adopted by the ‘bulls’ to support their long positions in the market were: (a) use of funds siphoned off from the banking sector, that has been flush with funds, for a long time; (b) transferring positions from one market to another, taking advantage of the asynchronous settlement cycles, and thereby avoiding having to take delivery of shares; (c) convincing the management of the companies whose shares were being bought to finance the purchases. There would have been no crisis had the markets kept going North, as was widely expected, after the presentation of the budget. However, that was not to be. The ‘bears’ in the market knew that the ‘bulls’ were sitting on a pin-head. They were extended to a point where even a slight downturn in the market could snap them. The onset of downturn in the world markets and the ‘tehelka’ episode could not have been timed better for the bears, and not surprisingly the market caved-in. The timing of the release of the report by SEBI is uncanny—after the end of the monsoon session of the parliament. This was done to ensure that the opposition did not have another weapon to hammer the already embattled Finance Minister. The release also coincides with the ‘kiss and make up’ attitude the government is suddenly advocating (remember the reported statement of the FM in the context of the scam that ‘there would be no witch hunt’ after the recent meet at the PM’s residence to discuss measures to revive the economy!). Based on the excerpts made available to the media, the inanity of SEBI’s findings is breathtaking! While there were perhaps technical violations of some of the regulations, the reported value of sale by the ‘bear cartel’ is simply not large enough to have caused a collapse of the market. The values of transactions assessed in the report of one of the main entities being investigated for the fall in prices is about Rs 20 crores per day. In the case of another, the value of sales assessed after obtaining privileged information is a mere Rs 3.9 crores. At a time when the combined volumes of transactions at the NSE and the BSE were running at about Rs 7000 crores per day, it is unbelievable that the above volumes could have caused the slide in values that actually occurred. The report documents in great detail the manner in which prices of scrips of a few companies were relentlessly manipulated through circular and dummy deals in the market. The participants in such exercises were not just brokers but several overseas corporate bodies or OCBs and at least one FII. Unfortunately, while the report would make an excellent bed-side reading, the evidence lacks the rigour required to nail the perpetrators of the manipulations in the court of law. As the lawyer of Ketan Parekh is reported to have said, the only violation that his client can be found legally guilty of is the Rs 137 crore pay-order scam involving the Bank of India. The report raises concerns of two kinds. The first pertains to prudential supervision by SEBI of markets. Influencing prices through circular and dummy deals is one of the most important market manipulations that SEBI is expected to monitor and control. What was it doing when these were actually taking place in the market? It is clear that SEBI failed in its supervisory role on this count. In some sense, the report is an indictment of SEBI itself! The second concern pertains to the fact that the evidence gathered by SEBI does not build a case against the guilty that cannot be challenged legally. It therefore appears that even on this occasion the guilty will finally go unpunished. What is the value of a reprimand to an entity, no matter how severe, if the entity is permitted to continue its business as before? The report raises the oft-stated shortcoming of our regulators. They are essentially toothless tigers, which can only growl, but cannot bite. Or, am I missing the point altogether? Aren’t all investigations in this great nation of ours an exercise in obfuscation of evidence so that the guilty go unpunished after appropriate deals have been struck and payments made in the right quarters? One will have to wait to answer this question. If the final report of SEBI is as innocuous as the second interim report, then the answer would surely be YES. Source: Economic Times, 11 September 2001. with crises in the financial sector and initiated multipronged investigations involving several agencies such as SEBI, RBI, CBI (Central Bureau of Investigations), DCA (Department of Companies Affairs), Enforcement Directorate, Directorate of Revenue and Intelligence, and the IT (Income Tax) department. The 1992 response was repeated, under pressure from the opposition parties, and a Joint Parliamentary Committee (JPC) has also been set up to investigate the scam of 2001. The multiplicity of investigating agencies typically leads to chaos and delays 174 India Infrastructure Report 2002 in investigations. The government also set up a special court in 1992 to speed up resolution of court cases connected with the 1992 scam. Despite that, nine years since the occurrence of the scam, most of the cases are still to be decided by the courts. The speed with which the crisis arising from rogue trading in the financial markets by a dealer of Barings plc was dealt with by the Singapore government provides a sharp contrast to the Indian government’s inability to deal with crises in the financial sector in India. In less than a week the crisis was resolved, with an organized take-over of Barings plc and jail sentence for Nick Leeson, the rogue trader. Similarly, the decisive intervention by the US Federal Reservor in 1998 ensured orderly winding down of the troubled hedge fund LTCM (Long Term Capital Management) and defused a potentially global crisis in the financial markets. The impact of the crisis on financial markets was effectively contained. In India, however, such crises invariably significantly impair the financial infrastructure for long periods. The financial markets were badly crippled for several years by the ‘tainted’ shares created by the scam of 1992. And now even before the aftershocks from the 1992 scam could subside, the financial markets have been hit by another scam. There is little reason to believe that the aftereffects from the recent scam would be any less severe than the one that occurred in 1992. basic inter-connected nature of operations of different segments. • If multiplicity of regulators makes it impossible to achieve such harmonization, then there is a case for unification of regulation under one regulatory authority that would have jurisdiction over the entire financial sector. • The regulatory agencies today are assigned the task of both supervision and regulation and development of the financial infrastructure. There is a need to separate the two functions. • There is an urgent need to strengthen the prudential supervision through extensive use of appropriate statistical tools for data analysis to anticipate and defuse a developing crisis. With the advancement in the information and communication technologies, such analyses can be carried out even on a real time basis, if required. • There is an urgent need to establish a speedier process for dealing with frauds committed in the operation of the financial infrastructure. If required, the government should setup a separate entity with legal powers to deal with white-collar crimes. • There is a need for professionalization of the management of the financial infrastructure as well as extensive involvement of professionals in the governance of the infrastructure created. As in other spheres, the bureaucratic and political interventions must cease in the operation and regulation of financial infrastructure. SUMMARY A credible and effective governance structure is the key to efficient functioning of financial infrastructure. Without this, achieving sustained growth in the creation of real infrastructure and high economic growth would remain a pipe dream for the nation. While several individuals and a few organizations bore the brunt of penal action arising from the scams, the regulators have typically escaped without having to pay a price. The euphemistic phrase ‘system failure’ is invariably used to describe regulatory failures and hide glaring shortcomings in the governance structure. The article reproduced in Box 6.5.1 highlights the shortcomings of investigations of scams and the break down of governance of the financial sector in the country. There have been significant additions to the financial infrastructure in the country in the last decade. As a result, the facilities available, on paper, in the financial sector, are almost comparable to those available in the developed countries. These facilities, however, are unable to deliver the goods because of the faulty governance structure for their operations. Based on the analysis of the three scams/ crises presented above, the measures required to strengthen the framework for governance are summarized below. • There is an urgent need to harmonize the regulations for different segments of the financial sector to reflect the 6.6 IS BRIBERY WELFARE-PROMOTING? Praveen Kulshreshtha During the past several decades, governments in India and in many other developing and transitional economies distributed essential commodities such as food and fuel among the population at low prices and on a first-come- first-served basis (rationing-by-waiting). Elaborate bureaucratic procedures as well as recurring delays on the part of bureaucrats only added to people’s woes, leading to greater uncertainty and longer periods of waiting. The Regulatory and Contractual Framework 175 presence of large waiting times led to the creation of thriving illegal markets which involved additional payments to middlemen as well as bribe-taking by bureaucrats who were in charge of distributing the commodities, in return for reduced waiting times17. Despite the fact that commodities were often in shortsupply, governments continued charging low prices for commodities on account of equity concerns and a desire to reach the poor. Bribery often led to fast and efficient provision of essential commodities to individuals who had the ability and willingness to pay bribes. However, the poorest of the poor still faced long queues and large waiting times, and in many cases, were unable to obtain the commodities. Following the onset of widespread economic reforms in India in the early 1990s, there was a marked change in the distribution of essential commodities. The government started offering ‘Tatkal’-like schemes to consumers in various forms, which essentially involved a greater price, or premium, in return for reduced, or zero, waiting time to obtain a good18. In general, differential pricing schemes (high prices corresponding to lower waiting times) are now being frequently used to improve the efficiency in the allocation of essential commodities and to enhance social welfare. One can argue that differential pricing schemes are superior to illegal markets involving bribery because in such schemes, the higher price, or premium, is paid directly to the government, who can use it either to cover its distribution costs, or to finance other social welfare programmes. In contrast, with bribery, middlemen and bureaucrats simply usurp the higher payment (bribe) for personal gain. Bribery is also strongly opposed on ethical grounds. However, in the past, arguments favouring bribery have also come about. Since the early 1960s, various social scientists (Leff 1964; Huntington 1968) have asserted that bribes act like ‘speed money’, or that bribery helps consumers reduce large and costly waiting times that arise in public distribution of goods and services. Moreover, researchers such as Lui (1985) and Rose-Ackerman (1978) have used theoretical models of queuing to show that under some general circumstances, bribery improves efficiency 17 Debroy et al. (1994a, b) conducted two independent questionnaire surveys to document the waiting times as well as illegal payments associated with obtaining essential commodities in the mid-1990s. De Soto (1989) similarly documented illegal and informal markets in Peru. 18 Such parallel pricing schemes have been used earlier in some cases such as for passports and telephone connections. See Debroy et al. (1994a, b). However, it is only over the last few years that such schemes have been widely introduced and used to tackle the problem of distribution of essential commodities. and enhances social welfare in the allocation of commodities 19. It is our contention that the above claim fails to hold in rationing-by-waiting situations where the official price of the rationed commodity is kept low for reasons of equity and reaching the poor. Using a simple framework to illustrate our ideas, we show that although bribery leads to greater efficiency and social welfare at prices which are not reasonably low, it does not improve efficiency and lowers the welfare of the poor at the expense of the rich in rationing-by-waiting at low prices20. If the rationed commodity is in great short-supply, the poor can even be excluded from obtaining the rationed commodity at low prices due to bribery. A BASIC FRAMEWORK OF RATIONING-BY-WAITING Let us consider a simple rationing situation where the government distributes an indivisible commodity at a fixed price P. For simplicity, suppose that individual incomes are distributed uniformly in the range zero to Y, where Y is the maximum possible individual income in society. For the sake of convenience, let us suppose that Y equals 1. To make things interesting, let us assume that each individual can buy upto one unit of the commodity, either by law, or due to preference21. However, the rationed commodity can be supplied only to a fraction S of the population, and hence is in short-supply. Now, consider a typical scenario where the fraction of buyers at the given price P exceeds S. This implies that there is ‘excess demand’ at P, or P is below the ‘market-clearing’ price. Since the commodity is distributed on a first-come-firstserved basis, a queue is expected to form, with individuals arriving before the counter opens. Individuals who arrive early enough are expected to get the commodity, while 19 However, later researchers such as Andvig (1991) have argued that queuing processes can be immensely complex and different ways of creating and managing queues can result in different outcomes regarding average waiting times (see also Bardhan 1997). Hence, they try to argue that bribery may not always enhance allocational efficiency in queuing situations. 20 The framework described here is a simplified version of the model presented in Kulshreshtha (2000). The basic model of rationing-by-waiting was developed in Barzel (1974). 21 See Gabszewicz and Thisse (1979) and Atkinson (1995)) for use of similar assumptions. However, individuals may illegally obtain several units of the commodity. According to Debroy et al. (1994b), commercial truck drivers in India tend to obtain about 5 licences at a point in time. When caught by a traffic inspector for a violation, they can either pay a fine, or turn in their licence to be picked up later from the police station. This is where having more than one licence is useful. When all five licences have been turned in, a new set of five licences is obtained. 176 India Infrastructure Report 2002 those who arrive later than others may fail to obtain it. In short, waiting can help to clear the market. In fact, if there are a large number of potential buyers and information regarding individual waiting times is freely and easily available, the individual waiting time needed to obtain the good is determined by the market (that is, no single individual can control the waiting time necessary to obtain the good)22. Hence, the waiting time that clears the market (‘equilibrium’ waiting time) is expected to be uniform across individuals. Figures 6.6.1 and 6.6.2 depict possible situations in the rationed good market. We plot individual incomes on the horizontal axis and individual satisfaction levels (corresponding to individual incomes) on the vertical axis. We assume for the moment that there is no bribery in the market. Therefore, an individual has two options: he/she can choose not to obtain the good (and hence not to join the queue), in which case he/she spends his/her income on other goods, deriving satisfaction UO, which for simplicity is taken as equal to income itself. Or, the individual can choose to join the queue, wait to obtain the rationed good and derive satisfaction UQ. To make things interesting, let us suppose that possessing the rationed good affects individual satisfaction in two ways. First, it enhances satisfaction regardless of income by an amount V, reflected in the vertical intercept of the UQ line. Second, it can also augment the satisfaction derived from income spent on other goods (‘other income’) by a factor b (>1), which is reflected in the greater than unity slope of UQ as in Fig. 6.6.123. However, waiting dampens both of these affects, resulting in a lower vertical intercept as well as lower slope of the UQ line. In fact, as Fig. 6.6.2 shows, the slope of UQ can become less than unity because of the disutility of waiting. Finally, note that the waiting time in the market adjusts until the fraction of individuals in the population who prefer to wait and obtain the rationed good (that is, those with incomes such that UQ > UO) equals S. The uniform ‘market-clearing’ or ‘equilibrium’ waiting time is denoted t*. RATIONING-BY-WAITING IN THE PRESENCE OF BRIBERY: EFFICIENCY AND WELFARE IMPLICATIONS Let us consider what happens if there is bribery in the rationed good market. In its simplest form, bribery gives rise to a parallel black market, with bureaucrats selling a part of the rationed good supply (S) in exchange for a fixed 22 Hence, waiting time is analogous to the uniform market price in a competitive market. 23 For instance, possessing a ration card, or passport allows an individual to carry out transactions that require a proof of identity, hence raising individual satisfaction from other trades and transactions. bribe b per unit (in addition to charging the official price P)24. Moreover, no waiting is needed to obtain the good via bribery25. Figures 6.6.3 and 6.6.4 show how the outcome in the rationed good market is altered due to bribery. The line UB captures the satisfaction levels of potential bribers in the population, for a given bribe b. Note that the slope of UB is b (>1), since there is no waiting associated with obtaining the good via bribery. In Fig. 6.6.3, where P is greater than or equal to V/b, individuals with incomes greater than, or equal to yQO are willing to queue up to get the rationed good (since UQ > UO). However, individuals with incomes greater than or equal to yBQ would prefer to pay the bribe instead of waiting (since UB > UQ). Hence, there is a switch from waiting to bribery for individuals at the upper end of the income distribution (that is, those with incomes exceeding yBQ). Clearly, as Fig. 6.6.3 shows, bribers are better off (that is, obtain a higher satisfaction level) in the presence of bribery, as there is no waiting time associated with bribery. But, what about the individuals who still queue up to obtain the rationed good (that is, those with incomes between yQO and yBQ)? Recall that in Fig. 6.6.3 (where bribery is present) as well as in Fig. 6.6.1 (where bribery is absent), price P is great than or equal to V/b and all individuals with incomes exceeding (1 – s) are willing to obtain the rationed good. The only difference between the two cases is that some of the rich buyers switch from waiting to bribery, when the latter becomes possible. However, the equilibrium waiting time t* remains the same in both cases (If the waiting time changes, the UQ line shifts in both cases and hence the fraction of rational good buyers no longer equals S). In other words, bribery does not affect the waiting time in the market and hence, the queuing individuals are not worse off because of bribery. Thus, bribery makes some individuals (the bribers) better off, while leaving others (the queuing and nonbuying population) no worse off. In other words, bribery eliminates costly waiting time for some individuals, while 24 Given that there are a large number of individuals in the population, it is likely that bureaucrat cannot learn each individual’s income. Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that he charges a uniform bribe b to all individuals who are willing to bribe. Moreover, for simplicity, we assume that the bureaucrat is not caught taking a bribe, or equivalently, the cost to him/her of bribe-taking is very low (not an unrealistic assumption, given the pervasiveness of bribery in many developing countries). 25 It is reasonable to assume that the bureaucrat distributes the bribed units randomly. However, in case the number of bribers exceed the number of units sold via bribery, it is expected that the bureaucrat will simply raise the bribe until there is no excess number of bribers. Regulatory and Contractual Framework 177 UQ U U UO UQ V(1 – t*) V(1 – t*) Utility/Satisfaction Utility/Satisfaction UO 0 0 P Income 1 – S Fig. 6.6.1 1 P Y P ≥ V/b 26 An outcome is said to enhance social efficiency if it makes some individuals better off while making nobody worse off. Also, note that bribery can be made completely redundant if the government raises the official price to PMC, or the ‘market-clearing’ price for the given S (see Fig. 6.6.3). This is because, by definition, no buyer needs to wait to obtain the good at PMC (reflected in the UMC line which is parallel to the UB line), while the set of buyers remains the same as at any other P ≥ V/b. Therefore, the outcome at PMC is preferred by all buyers to the outcome at any other P in the above range, since (costly) waiting time is eliminated for each buyer at PMC. Income 1 Y Q Q affecting nobody else adversely. Hence, we can conclude that bribery improves efficiency and enhances social welfare in the queuing situation described above26. However, it can be shown that the market outcome is strikingly different in the case where price P is less than V/b. Figure 6.6.4 illustrates that at prices in the above range, individuals who can afford the rationed good (incomes no less than P) but have incomes less than yQO prefer to queue up, while those with incomes exceeding yBO (> yQO) prefer to pay the bribe and obtain the good. Note that in the absence of bribery, all individuals with incomes between P and (P + S) (> yQO) will obtain the good via waiting (see Fig. 6.6.2). Hence, it is clear that via bribery, some of the available units are siphoned off to the relatively rich individuals (those with incomes greater than yBO), leaving less units for the relatively poor individuals (those with incomes between P and (P + S)) who would have obtained the good via waiting in the absence of bribery. This results in greater competition among the poor individuals who P + S Fig. 6.6.2 P < V/b would wait and therefore, the equilibrium waiting time goes up (as depicted in Fig. 6.6.4 by a downward rotation of the UQ line). As a consequence, some individuals (those with incomes between yQO and (P + S)) decide to leave the market altogether, due to the disutility of higher waiting time. Thus, when the official price of the commodity is lower than V/b, bribery results in greater benefit for the rich who bribe (because they are able to obtain the rationed good without waiting) while the waiting poor face a loss (because their waiting time is increased). Hence, we can say that bribery does not enhance social efficiency and may not increase social welfare because it makes the bribing rich better off, but at the expense of the waiting poor who are worse off due to bribery. In fact, it can be shown that when the rationed good is in extreme short-supply (S is lower than some critical value), the bureaucrat finds it optimal to choose a bribe such that all units are sold to bribers and hence, all waiting individuals are excluded from the market. Hence, bribery can benefit some rich individuals but may lead to exclusion of all waiting poor. CONCLUSION We have shown above that contrary to earlier assertions, bribery may not enhance social efficiency and promote social welfare in rationing-by-waiting situations. Although bribery can have beneficial efficiency and welfare 178 India Infrastructure Report 2002 UB UMC UQ UB U U UO UQ Utility/Satisfaction Utility/Satisfaction UO V(1 – t*) V V(1 – t*) V 0 P Income PMC YQO = P + b 1 – S Q Fig. 6.6.3 YBQ 1 Y B P ≥ V/b implications in cases where price of rationed commodity is not very low, it fails to achieve overall positive results in situations where the commodity is priced low, which is the most common scenario in developing and transitional economies in the past. The above result raises two issues. First, we have shown that if a rationed good is in limited supply, bribery leads to competition among bribers (who wish to reduce costly waiting time) and the waiting poor to obtain the good. If bribery prevails at low prices, the poor can get excluded from the market. However, one can argue that if bribery was not allowed, then at low prices it is the rich who would be excluded from the market instead (as depicted in Fig. 6.6.2). This is because the poor are more willing to wait at low prices than the rich (since the poors’ disutility, or cost of waiting, is less). If the commodity is an essential one, such as electricity, or water, exclusion of the rich is as much of a concern as exclusion of the poor. The crux of the problem here lies in the fact that the commodity is in limited, or short-supply. The solution to bribery and the consequent problem of exclusion lies partly in raising the supply of the rationed commodity, while creating avenues by which willing individuals can pay to obtain the rationed good without waiting, or waiting less. One way to do so is to introduce differential pricing schemes in the allocation of essential commodities, while increasing the overall supply of the commodities. It can 0 P YQO Q Fig. 6.6.4 P + b YBO Income 1 Y B P < V/b be shown, and is an intuitive proposition, that differential pricing will lead to lower bribery in rationing-by-waiting situations. This is because the rich can find an easy substitute for bribery in the higher-price schemes, where the good is distributed instantaneously, or the waiting is reduced substantially, in lieu of the increase in the commodity’s supply. The second issue that can be raised here is that bribery may continue to prevail despite the prevalence of differential pricing schemes, if the bureaucrats can influence the waiting times of individuals by creating delays, or wasteful redtape. If bureaucrats cannot be monitored well, they would have an incentive to use wasteful red-tape to create a demand for bribery. By creating delays, bureaucrats can impose large waiting costs on individuals even when there is no a priori reason for waiting times to be large (that is, when the rationed good is not in great short-supply). Thus, if waiting time is endogenous, that is, can be influenced by bureaucrats, bribery can arise even in the presence of differential pricing schemes, or more generally, when the rationed good is in greater supply. This possibility, which is observed quite commonly in many developing and transitional countries suffering from rampant bribery and corruption, calls for greater monitoring and control of bureaucrats via anti-corruption policies, in addition to the use of differential pricing schemes to reduce the scope of bribery in rationing-by-waiting situations. Regulatory and Contractual Framework 179 6.7 THE ENRON DISASTER Prayas Energy Group* Enron, an American multinational corporation, made its first entry into the Indian electricity sector in June 1992 by signing a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) with the power utility owned by the Government of Maharashtra, viz. the Maharashtra State Electricity Board (MSEB). The first Power Purchase Agreement (PPA) was signed by the Dabhol Power Company (DPC), the Indian subsidiary of Enron, and MSEB in 1993. This became controversial with allegations of corruption in the deal. The incumbent government in the state was defeated in the subsequent elections. The new government promptly cancelled the deal after assuming power in March 1995. However, it renegotiated the deal with Enron, with equal promptness. The amended PPA was finally signed in July 1996 and was further amended in a substantial manner as late as December 1998. Enron started commercial operation of the first stage of the power project (with capacity of about 700 MW) from May 1999. Though it is not utilizing the entire capacity of the Enron plant, MSEB was paying about Rs 95 crores per month to Enron as fixed capacity charges, irrespective of the amount of electricity it bought from Enron. This burden soon became unbearable for MSEB, which had already been in a precarious financial situation. Meanwhile, newspaper reports about the effective rate of Enron’s power, which was quoted as Rs 7.80 per unit [kWh], caused uproar in the state legislative assembly. The state government agreed to appoint a high-power expert committee to ‘review’ the deal. After a delay of more than six weeks, the Godbole Committee was appointed, which comprised of Madhav Godbole (Chairman), E.A.S. Sarma, Deepak Parikh, R.K. Pachauri, Kirit Parikh, and V.M. Lal. See Box 6.7.1 for a Summary of the Committee findings. It would be appropriate to record two important observations regarding the Committee at the beginning. First, though many people raised protests that some members of the Committee had a pro-Enron bias, there cannot be any doubt that the Committee possessed a very high-level of expertise and experience in the areas that were crucial in this matter, viz. energy policy, infrastructure finance, international trade and public administration. Second, it is worth noting that all the members came from mainstream institutions, and none could be branded as having anti-privatization or anti-reforms leanings. The report of the Committee should be viewed in the background of these two distinctions, which make it clear that the proEnron quarters do not have a basis to protest about the composition of this Committee. THE MALADY This story of greed, deception, and intrigue is not restricted only to the Enron project. Similar stories and criticisms are being heard about other projects started by the independent power producers (IPPs). Further, it needs to be noted that the Enron project (as well as the other IPP projects) is just one symptom or outburst of the malady that is plaguing the entire Indian power sector. MSEB, like all other SEBs, is experiencing severe crisis. The questions raised by the report of the Godbole Committee, the broad governance failure, and the widespread malady destroying the Indian power sector need to be analysed with an integrated perspective. This is especially important when the sector is being reformed and restructured in a fundamental manner. The integrated analysis should begin with investigation into the question of why were ‘the broad governance failure’ and the three crises allowed to happen and persist. These must have been allowed because some people, who are powerful enough, benefit handsomely out of this rot, while the sector in general and most of the consumers suffered very badly. Further, those who have been benefiting have adequate control over the sector to perpetrate this rot, despite the resultant destruction and suffering for many.27 It is often and quite rightly said that at the root of this performance crisis lies the ‘political interference’, to be more correct, interference by partisan interests represented by politicians. But the politicians are not alone in this game. In fact, they are only one of the key players in the alliances (and nexuses), who turn even a genuine project into a disaster and a dishonest project into a death trap (as happened in the case of the Enron project). The other key players in these alliances include sections of top-level bureaucrats, contractors, suppliers, officials, employees, and even some consumers. Obviously, members of these unholy alliances work to serve their own interests by drawing maximum possible economic and political benefits in every possible way. 27 * An NGO based in Pune working for consumer and civil society rights in energy and infrastructure. In fact, they must be powerful enough not only to repress the marginalized sufferers but even to silence the powerful ones who are not willing to join them. 180 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Box 6.7.1 The Godbole Committee’s Findings The Committee submitted the first part of its report on 10 April 2001. The report was extremely critical about the current agreements and the process in which the agreements were cleared and passed by various government agencies as well as the concerned autonomous agencies. Here we bring out the findings and conclusions of the committee on the substantive aspect of the PPA for Enron’s DPC project as well as those on the process in which the agreement was cleared (Government of Maharashtra 2001). (All figures in brackets in the subsequent discussion refer to the page numbers in the Godbole Committee Report). Substantive Problems with the PPA Instead of discussing, in detail, the findings of the Committee on the substantive aspects of the agreements, this paper outlines the conclusive comments of the Committee only on the four major substantive issues in order to maintain brevity. The Inappropriate Project and Unwanted Electricity ‘The Committee finds that, while the initial demand projections for DPC were flawed in that they ignored different load types in their projections, the demand projection that was the basis for commencement of Phase II was based on patently untenable assumptions, given the information at that time; assumption that have since proved to be completely unjustified’ (emphasis original) (53). The Unnecessary Linkages with Supporting Projects with Excessive Capacities The Committee points out that various components of the complex Enron project other than the power project such as the LNG Regassification Facility, Marine Facilities, Shipping Charter and Gas-Supply Agreement were unnecessarily linked to the power project. Further, it also observes that the designed capacities of all these supporting or connected projects were in excess of the needs of the power project. It also points out that the cost of these overcapacities were loaded entirely on the power project (and hence on MSEB). Surreptitious Overcharging of Rs 930 Crores per Year The most shocking revelation of the report is the surreptitious overcharging done by Enron on at least four counts (with yearly excess payment figures in the brackets): (i) unnecessary capacity of the LNG facility (Rs 253 crores); (ii) charges for the harbour facilities and shipping charter (Rs 100 crores); (iii) excessive operati on and maintenance expenses (Rs 246 crores); (iv) inflated fuel consumption (Rs 332 crores). Thus, even within the framework of the present agreement, it could be claimed that DPC is overcharging MSEB by about Rs 930 crores per year. Unaffordability: Impacts on State Finances The Committee unanimously arrives at the conclusion that, in one year, the payments to DPC have ruined the financial position of MSEB and put a heavy burden on the finances of the state government. This prompts the Committee to comment: ‘This (burden of Enron payment) could conceivably lead to drastic cut in budget allocations for the “State Plan” expenditure and can arguably lead to a declaration of a Plan Holiday’ (24). Problems in the Process of Sanctioning the Project As mentioned before, the Committee also recorded severe criticisms of the process in which the project was sanctioned. The process related criticisms are of direct relevance. The ‘Fast Track’ Process of the Renegotiation Group While discussing the speed at which the Renegotiation Group functioned, the Committee quotes from the judgement of the Bombay High Court: ‘The speed at which the whole thing was done by the negotiating group is unprecedented. What would stop one to say, as was said by the Chief Minister in the context of the original PPA, “Enron revisited, Enron saw and Enron conquered—much more that it did earlier”’ (39). Negotiation vs. Bidding The state government had persistently defended the choice of the route of negotiations over the more transparent route of competitive bidding. It has argued in the court that competitive bidding was not relevant, counterproductive and inappropriate. The Godbole Committee found ‘(E)ach of these reasons to be deficient and suspect’ (43). The state government has also argued that it had conducted intense negotiations before signing the contract. The Committee commented: ‘Both, the justifications and the quality of these negotiations are suspect’ (emphasis original) (42). Central Electricity Authority (CEA) Clearances The Committee points out that, contrary to its regular practice, the CEA, in its relevant letter, did not explicitly give the required ‘techno-economic’ clearance to the Enron project. Neither, at any stage, did the CEA indicate that it reviewed the economic aspects of the project. This prompts the Committee to comment: ‘Thus, it is a moot question whether the CEA discharged the statutory duty cast on it under the Electricity Supply Act adequately. It is not clear from all this whether the economic aspects of the project have been comprehensively evaluated’ (48). Tariff Competitiveness: A Fraud on the Public Interest In order to satisfy the legal requirement and also to establish that the project is in public interest, it was necessary to demonstrate that Enron’s tariff would be competitive. Further, in order to demonstrate its competitiveness, Enron’s tariff should be demonstrated to be lower than the tariff for an equivalent project according to the central government norms. After detailed investigation into this issue of competitiveness, the Committee comments: ‘Thus, in each and every instance, both for Phase I and Phase II, the assumptions are not only untenable; they are also favorable to DPC. . . . The Committee considers this combination of circumstances to be beyond the realm of coincidence Regulatory and Contractual Framework 181 and thereby is constrained to conclude that these assumptions were deliberately chosen so as to show that the DPC tariff was lower than GoI tariff. As can be seen, the entire demonstration of public interest owing to the lower DPC tariff is on extremely shaky ground and in the opinion of the Committee utterly unsustainable’ (emphasis original) (61). Lack of Due Diligence by DPC and Financial Institution The Committee found severe lapses on the part of the financial institutions that provided funds to the Enron project: ‘The Committee also finds that the financial institutions showed poor judgement and lack of due diligence in accepting these (demand) projections without demur . . . The decision of the financial institutions to fund this project seems to have been based primarily on escrow account given by MSEB, guarantee by the state government and the counter-guarantee by the central government (for Phase I) rather than on an independent and meticulous appraisal of the project’ (53). The ‘Broad’ Failure of Governance The Committee says: ‘The Committee is troubled with the failure of governance that seems to have characterized almost every step of the decision making process on matters relating to DPC. This failure of governance has been broad, across different government at different points of time, at both the state and the central level, and across different agencies associated with examining the project, and at both the administrative and political levels. It strains belief to accept that such widespread and consistent failure to execute assigned responsibilities is purely coincidental’ (84). These startling, if not shocking, observations and findings of the Committee comprised of the men of high expertise and experience should certainly give a severe jolt to every right thinking citizen. Obviously, the entire Enron saga could prove to be an illustrative case study for the students of public affairs. The subsequent part of the paper draws lessons for governance from this saga. There are many examples of such unholy alliances operating in the Indian power sector and drawing benefits for their members. As is evident in the case of the Enron project, the political bosses, top-level bureaucrats, and Enron joined hands to throw to the winds every legal provision that posed even the slightest hurdle for the project. But the next question is how exactly did these unholy alliances manage to do this? As the analysis of the Enron deal by the Godbole Committee suggests, these alliances and nexuses effectively take control of one or many of the three main functions of the governance process: (i) decision making, (ii) implementation of the decisions made, and (iii) regulation (ensuring adherence to rules) of the decision making and implementation functions. These three governance functions, in normal circumstances, are expected to work to serve the public interest.28 However, by taking over the control of these three governance functions, the members and leaders of these unholy alliances and nexuses ensure that, instead of the public interest, the sector would function to mainly serve their own interests. In this sense, there is a breakdown of the governance of the sector. In other words, we can describe this situation as the crisis of governance in the sector. Thus, we can conclude that at the root of the performance crisis (as well as that of credibility and financial crises) lies the governance crisis. Lack of Transparency The answers to these questions could be provided in terms of the three lacunae in governance, which are discussed 28 Here, the term public interest is used in a somewhat broader sense. It includes interests of the disadvantaged sections of society plus the broader and long-term interests of society as a whole. in the following paragraphs. These alliances manage to take control of the sector primarily because they can manage to avoid examination of the propriety and rationality of the decisions. This is possible because the alliances not only manage to hide all this information about the decisions but also deceive people by giving false information. The Enron saga provides a plethora of illustrations to support this observation.29 This lack of information (or provision of misinformation) on crucial aspects of the decisions or their implementation points at the first lacuna, viz. lack of transparency, that allows the unholy alliances to take the control of governance of the sector. Lack of Accountability towards the Public The second lacuna relates to the lack of accountability of those who make the decisions or implement them. There are many instances in which the politicians, bureaucrats, and experts who made the decisions that proved to have seriously adverse impacts on public interest could not be forced to own up to their responsibilities and to pay for their unjustifiable, irrational, and blatantly anti-people decisions. This was again well illustrated in the Enron saga.30 29 Take the example of the separation of the regassification facility as per the recommendation of the Renegotiation Group in 1995. MSEB and Enron (and possibly the Government of Maharashtra) decided among themselves not to follow this recommendation without informing the public about this decision to deviate. This is despite the fact that the reduction in capital cost due to this separation was one of the main arguments put forth by the state government to justify the renegotiated deal. 30 The pro-Enron politicians and bureaucrats claimed that Enron’s tariff would be Rs 1.89 per unit (in the case of the first 182 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Lack of Public Participation There is another critical lacuna in the current governance process, especially in the decision making and regulatory functions. It has been clearly established that the major decisions are, in most cases, made by a small coterie comprised of politicians in power, top-level bureaucrats and their commercial consultants, all coming from the advantaged and largely urban sections of society. In effect, most of their decisions reflect not only their limited understanding of the socio-politico-economic reality at the ground level but also result in welfare of the advantaged sections. This lack of participation of diverse sections of society with different socio-politico- economic backgrounds provides scope for the unholy alliances to serve their own narrow interests at the cost of public interest. To sum up, because of the lack of transparency, the lack of accountability of decision makers and executors of these decisions, and the lack of public participation in decision making and regulation, it was possible for these unholy alliances to hold the sector for ransom. Thus, the breakdown of the governance of sector, or the ‘crisis of governance’ in the sector, is rooted in the lack of Transparency, Accountability and (Public) Participation (or TAP). Hence, lack of TAP is seen in this analysis as the core malady besetting the sector.31 THE REMEDY World Bank Model’s Limitations As far as the power relationship between the unholy alliances and the consumers (these include industrial consumers also) is concerned, privatization will certainly not make any PPA, Rs 2.40 per unit). When Enron started sending bills with an effective tariff of Rs 6.00 to Rs 7.80 per unit, it became clear that MSEB, the state government, and the economy of the state would soon be on the brink of financial disaster. However, all these decision makers and the implementers continue to espouse Enron’s cause. 31 This diagnostic analysis could be extended further. It must be noted at this point that, even in the earlier model (of the earlier era), there were certain provisions for TAP. For example, there has been a provision in the Electricity Act for establishment of a Consultative Council (CC), which is expected to advise the SEB on policy matters. Similarly, the decision makers in the sector were to be held accountable through the politicians who were the ultimate masters of the sector. These politicians were to be held accountable through democratic elections. However, the CCs were hardly functional, if at all they existed. This was because their formation and functioning has been left to the discretion of the SEBs. Similarly, the politicians devised many ways and tricks to win elections without being held accountable for their actions. This circumvention of the existing TAP related provisions was possible mainly because these provisions were indirect, vague, and discretionary. change in favour of the latter. In fact, there is a danger that with entry of the powerful corporations, the new and equally (if not more) powerful and equally unholy alliances of corporations, politicians, and bureaucrats might take control of the governance of the sector. The situation after the entry of Enron and other IPPs has demonstrated that this apprehension is not ill-founded. In a way, this is acknowledged even by the protagonists of privatization. They agree to the need for stringent and independent regulation to keep in check the ‘non-competitive behaviour’ of private players, especially in view of the natural monopoly in the Indian power sector, which is going to persist at least for some decades to come.32 However, there is one crucially distinctive characteristic of the independent regulation as envisaged by the proprivatization elements who largely subscribe to the World Bank’s model of electricity sector reforms. In this model, the regulation is to be independent of the state and ‘investorfriendly’. This is because the main objective guiding the design of the regulatory system in this scheme is to protect private players and investors from ‘interference’ of the state. Such a system will not automatically serve the purpose of protecting interests of consumers and people in general, and the disadvantaged sections in particular, from the designs of the unholy alliances. This is mainly because such a system does not pay necessary attention to the special needs of these sections, and does not emphasize on creating space for these sections in the regulatory process and on building their capabilities to utilize this space. This effectively excludes the small consumers and disadvantaged sections from participating in the ‘independent’ regulatory system. Further, as our earlier study of the World Bank’s Orissa model demonstrates, the regulatory institutions in this are severely prone to sabotage by powerful vested interests (Dixit et al. 1998).33 Democratization To be more precise, these requirements should be articulated as: (i) complete transparency towards public (T); (ii) direct accountability primarily (not towards the investors but) towards public (A); and (iii) meaningful public participation (P). Thus, TAP is essentially ‘public-friendly’ as against the ‘investor-friendly’ TAP envisaged by the World Bank. 32 It is by now clear that despite the enthusiasm of some, it is quite difficult to bring in bulk competition in the Indian power sector without precipitating the attendant legal, procedural, and financial problems. There is no need to mention here that retail competition will remain a distant dream, if not an impossibility, in decades to come. 33 However, it needs to be acknowledged that there is some space for the public and consumers to intervene in the regulatory process. The new model is certainly better than the old, state centred model, at least in this respect. Regulatory and Contractual Framework 183 The Regulatory Commissions The practical way to approach this task is to begin with agencies that would be discharging the three governance functions. The regulatory commissions are products of the particular reform model that is tailored largely on the lines of the US model and actively sponsored by the World Bank. As mentioned before, the main function of the ‘independent’ regulatory commissions, as envisaged in the World Bank’s model, is to shield private players from the interference of the state and politicians. However, their American genealogy has left many provisions—which are conducive to ‘public-friendly’ TAP—intact in the structure and functioning of these regulatory commissions. As our experience in Maharashtra suggests, the available space for public-friendly TAP in the structure and functioning of the regulatory commission could still be effectively utilized to exercise public control, to a great extent, not only on the regulatory function but also on the decision making and implementation functions. Continued Role for the State However, in the Indian situation, many state governments, despite establishment of the regulatory commissions, have retained a considerable amount of decision making power, especially in the case of policy decisions. In addition, to make matters more complex, most of the state governments maintain ownership of the SEBs. There is a growing demand that these governments should hand over all the powers and responsibilities to the regulatory commissions, which are mentioned in the relevant reform Acts. However, at the same time, the demand for divesting even the policy making functions (that still remain with the state governments) and hand them over to the regulatory commissions might prove premature and counter-productive.34 TAPing the Governance Agencies As Table 6.7.1 indicates, all the three agencies—government, regulators and utilities—will be handling the decision 34 This observation is rooted, first, in our analysis of the structure of the regulatory system in Orissa, which was designed by the World Bank and found to be deficient on the grounds of ‘public-friendly’ TAP. It is feared that due to this lacuna, the regulators might turn into the new unrestrained kings of the sector (Dixit et al. 1998). The second reason for this caution is rooted in the fear that the regulatory commissions—because of their particular structure, mandate, and functioning style—will be much beyond the radius of influence of the disadvantaged sections of society. As against this, the state will be comparatively more amenable to influence of these sections, who, despite their disadvantages, have gained considerable political leveraging power in the five decades of not-so-perfect democratic activity. making function.35 The state will be handling mainly the policy related decisions, while the utilities will be making many important functional decisions in the techno-economic and financial areas. The regulatory commissions, however, will be adjudicating on major decisions such as tariff and propriety of investments. Further, while implementation function will be mainly handled by the utilities, the regulation function will be handled by the regulatory commissions.36 There are four main routes or mechanisms (or strategies) to fulfil the task of TAPing the three governance agencies. The first route is the ‘democratic-political’ means that are available in the democratic system. These means include activities such as submitting petition and organizing public education or protest programs. These are especially useful and effective in the case of publicly-owned utilities. Here, the term ‘democratic-political means’ needs to be differentiated from the term ‘political interference’, which essentially means interference by partisan politicians aimed at protecting narrow political or economic interest and not public interest. As against this, democratic-political means are used by various civil society institutions (CSIs) and individuals to put forth either public grievances or their own positions on public issues. The second route is the judicial route. The state agencies could be forced to respond to TAP related demands using many existing laws, for example, the law such as the newly enacted Right to Information Act.37 As far as the regulatory commissions are concerned, there is provision in all the reform Acts permitting judicial review of the decisions of the regulatory commissions.38 The third route is using the TAP mechanisms that are in-built in the structure and functioning of (especially of the publicly-owned) utilities, the state, and the regulatory commissions. As we have seen earlier, there have been certain in-built TAP related mechanisms in the government 35 Table 6.7.1 is aimed at providing a somewhat simple picture. Many intricacies and exceptions could be identified to make the picture more sophisticated. 36 Though there will be considerable diversity in the functioning of the State Electricity Regulatory Commissions or SERCs, the different strategies to address this diversity will not be discussed in this paper. 37 Though many observers have (rightly) expressed doubts over the efficacy of this set of new laws. However, a lot can be achieved by trying to enforce the existing provisions of these laws while pressing for changes in the laws. 38 However, in the case of most of the states where the World Bank consultants have drafted the Act, the Act allows review of the orders of the decisions of the commissions only on procedural grounds, precluding the substantive examination of the orders of the commissions. However, in the other states, the orders of the commissions are open to procedural as well as substantial review. 184 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Table 6.7.1 TAPing the Three Main Governance Agencies Governance agency Governance function(s) Utilities The State Regulatory Commissions Decision-making Implementation Regulation and the utilities, which are often given short shrift. CSIs should undertake concerted efforts to press for adherence to these in-built mechanisms. In the earlier era, the blatant avoidance of these mechanisms was, in fact, allowed to spread wide because of their neglect by CSIs. The fourth route is using the inter-agency pressures. Though not exactly designed with a comprehensive perspective, the three governing agencies keep each other in balance by exerting inter-agency pressures. For example, the regulatory commissions can pull up the governments, if it is demonstrated to them that certain actions on the part of the government encroach upon the decision-making powers of the commissions. Conversely, the governments can give policy directions to the commissions, if desired. The Two Preconditions: Space and Capabilities Our experience with the Maharashtra Electricity Regulatory Commission suggests that it is possible to TAP and to democratize governance agencies to varying degrees (functions) if the following two preconditions could be fulfilled. First, there should be legal and procedural ‘space’ for effective TAPing of the governance agencies. Second, the public (interest) institutions or civil society institutions should have the resources, information, and capabilities (expertise and skills) that are necessary to make optimum use of this available space. Creating the space (in terms of institutions, Acts, and rules) for TAPing of the governance agencies through appropriate legislation is a tougher task. This is very well demonstrated in the case of deceptive legislation that has been enacted in various states under the name of ‘Right to Information’ Act. In the case of the Indian power sector, the Central Reform Act (the Electricity Regulatory Commissions Act of 1998) and the state-level reforms Acts in most states allow, in principle, considerable space for TAPing regulatory commission and utilities. However, in some states, this space is not clearly articulated at the operational level in the design of the ‘Conduct of Business Rules’. This results mostly in leaving the TAP related provisions vague, indirect, and discretionary. Further, there Routes for TAPing the agency Through democratic ‘political’ means Through courts using laws (such as the ‘Right to Information’ Act) Through in-built TAP mechanism (such as the Consultative Councils and public proceedings) Through inter-agency pressures is a need to set the right procedural precedents to create and/or establish the TAP. The task, which is equally daunting, is to evolve the necessary capabilities (expertise and skills), resources, and attitudes in various social and political (or civil society) institutions in order to make the best use of the available space for TAP. Because governance of the power sector involves complex technological, economic, financial, and legal issues, in order to be effective, the civil society institutions would require information, analytical capabilities, and legal skills of highly sophisticated levels. All this also requires equally higher levels of human and financial resources. It needs to be understood that the structure, perspective, capabilities, skills, and resources possessed by most of the civil society institutions in India are geared to deal with the old, state-centred political and economic regime. To make changes in all these would require vision, concerted efforts, and leadership, all of which seem to be absent from the scene. CONCLUSION The major contribution of the Godbole Committee is in highlighting the ‘broad failure of governance’ as the root cause of the fraud and tragedy that struck the state of Maharashtra in the form of the Enron project. But, again, Enron is not alone. The story is not much different in the case of the other independent power producers (IPPs) in the country. Unfortunately, the prescription suggested by the mainstream institutions to resolve the prevailing crises— privatisation and independent regulations—are not appropriately designed to address the root cause of the governance crisis, viz. the control of unholy alliances. As a result, the crucial governance agencies in the new model, viz. the regulatory commissions, remain highly prone to sabotage by the unholy alliances of the vested interests. This leaves us no choice but to give centrality to the public-friendly TAP provisions in our efforts to reform and restructure the Indian power sector. This, in turn, would Regulatory and Contractual Framework 185 require that all the governance functions and governance agencies are made amenable, on mandatory basis, to full transparency to the public, direct accountability to public, and meaningful participation of public. The three major governance agencies—the state, the utilities, and the regulatory commissions—could be TAPed in a variety of ways. However, the space and capabilities of civil society institutions will be the important determinants of successful TAPing of these agencies. Improving on both these counts in a rapid manner is the main challenge facing the civil society in this country. Another challenge before the civil society in this country is to resist the attempts by the vested interests to urgently bulldoze major and irreversible changes in the structure and frameworks (including the ownership patterns) in the sector. REFERENCES Alderman, H. (1987), ‘Allocation of Goods through Non-pure Mechanisms: Evidence on Distribution by Willingness to Wait’, Journal of Development Economics, No. 25, pp. 105– 124. Andvig, J.C. (1991), ‘The Economics of Corruption: A Survey’, Studi Economici, Vol. 43, No. 1, pp. 57–94. Andvig, J.C. and K.O. Moene (1990), ‘How Corruption may Corrupt’, Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, Vol. 13, No. 1, pp. 63–76. Atkinson, A.B. (1995), ‘Capabilities, Exclusion and Supply of Goods’, in K. Basu, A. Pattanaik and K. Suzumura (eds.), Choice, Welfare and Development: A Festschrift in Honour of Amartya K. Sen, Oxford University Press, Delhi, pp. 17– 31. Banerjee, A.V. (1997), ‘A Theory of Misgovernance’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 4, pp. 1289–332. Bardhan, P. (1997), ‘Corruption and Development: A Review of Issues’, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 3, pp. 1320–46. Bardhan, P. and D. Mookherjee (1998), Expenditure Decentralization and the Delivery of Public Services in Developing Countries, University of California, Berkeley, mimeo. Barzel, Y. (1974), ‘A Theory of Rationing by Waiting’, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 18, No. 1, pp. 73–95. Beck, P.J. and M.W. Maher (1986), ‘A Comparison of Bribery and Bidding in Thin Markets’, Economic Letters, Vol. 20, pp. 1–5. Better Regulation Task Force (2001), Economic Regulators, available at http://www.cabinet-office.gov.uk/regulation/ TaskForce/2001/BRTF%20Economic%20Regulation.pdf. Brueckner, J. (1999), Fiscal Decentralization in LDCs: The Effect of Local Corruption and Tax Evasion, Univ. of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign, mimeo. Cadot, O. (1987), ‘Corruption as a Gamble’, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 33, No. 2, pp. 223–44. Chartered Accountants of Canada (the CICA) official website: http://www.cica.ca. Cleveland, F.A. and F.W. Powell (1909); Railroad Promotion and Capitalization in the United States, Longmans, reprinted 1966, Johnson Reprint Corporation, New York. De Soto, H. (1989), The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World, Harper & Row, New York. Debroy, B., A. Bardiya and V.N. Sivaraj (1994a), ‘Transactions costs: Ration Cards, Gas Connections, Telephone Connections, Passports and Driving Licences’, Project Large: Legal Adjustments and Reforms for Globalizing the Economy, New Delhi, Discussion Paper 4. Debroy, B., Bardiya, A. and V.N. Sivaraj (1994b), ‘Documenting Illegal Markets’, Project Large: Legal Adjustments and Reforms for Globalising the Economy, New Delhi, Discussion Paper 5. Dixit, Shantanu, Girish Sant and Subodh Wagle (1998), WB– Orissa Model of Power Sector Reforms: Cure Worse than the Disease, Economic and Political Weekly, 25 April, pp. 944–8. Dixit, Shantanu, Sant Girish and Wagle Subodh (1998), ‘WBOrissa Model of Power Sector Reforms: Cure Worse than Disease’, Economic and Political Weekly, 25 April. Dobbin, Frank (1994), Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Dornan, D.L. (2000), ‘GASB 34’s Impact on Infrastructure Management, Financing and Reporting’, Infrastructure Management Group Inc., June, (http://www.naco.org/gasb/ dornan.pdf). Dunn, Samuel O. (1913), Government Ownership of Railways, Appleton, New York, quoted in Dobbin (1994). Edmonds, C. (2001), ‘Warren Buffet feels the power’, TheStreet.com, available at http://www.thestreet.com/comment/ powerlines/1404841.html. Eichengreen, B. (1994), ‘Financing Infrastructure in Developing Countries; Lessons from the Railway Age’, Policy Research Working Paper 1379, Background Paper for World Development Report 1994, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Fisman, R. and R. Gatti (1999), ‘Decentralization and Corruption: Cross-Country and Cross-State Evidence’, draft Working Paper, World Bank, Washington, D.C., mimeo. Gabstewicz, J.J. and J.-F. Thisse (1979), ‘Price Competition, Quality and Income Disparities’, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 340–59. Government of Maharashtra (2001), Report of the Energy Review Committee (Part I), April, Mumbai. Chaired by Madhav Godbole (popularly called the Godbole Committee Report). Governmental Accounting Standards Board (1984), GASB Statement No. 1: Authoritative Status of NCGA Pronouncements and AICPA Industry Audit Guide, Norwalk, CT, July. Governmental Accounting Standards Board (1990), GASB Statement No. 11: Measurement Focus and Basis of Accounting—Governmental Fund Operating Statements, Norwalk, CT, May. 186 India Infrastructure Report 2002 Governmental Accounting Standards Board (1993), GASB Statement No. 17: Measurement Focus and Basis of Accounting—Governmental Fund Operating Statements: Amendment of the Effective Dates of GASB Statement No. 11 and Related Statements—An Amendment of GASB Statements No. 10, 11, and 13, Norwalk, CT, June. Governmental Accounting Standards Board (1999), GASB Statement No. 34: Basic Financial Statements—and Management’s Discussion and Analysis—for State and Local Governments, Norwalk, CT, June. Haskins, C. (2001), ‘The Over-Mighty Regulators’, Financial Times, 12 July. Huntington, S.P. (1968), Political Order in Changing Societies, Yale Univ. Press, New Haven. International Federation of Accountants (IFAC) (2000), Government Financial Reporting, Accounting Issues and Practices (Study 11), New York, NY, May. International Federation of Accountants (IFAC) (2000), Preface to International Public Sector Accounting Standards, New York, NY, May. Kangle, R.P. (1972), The Kautilya Arthasastra, Part II, University of Bombay, Bombay. Keenan, J. (1997), ‘Tangible, but transitional’, CA Magazine, September, pp. 32–3. Klitgaard, R.E. (1988), Controlling Corruption, Univ. of California Press, Berkeley. Krueger, A.O. (1974), ‘The Political Economy of Rent-Seeking Society’, American Economic Review, Vol. 64, pp. 291–303. Kulshreshtha, P. (2000), ‘A Model of Rationing by Waiting in the Presence of Bribery’, mimeograph, Madras School of Economics. Leff, N.H., (1964), ‘Economic Development through Bureaucratic Corruption’, The American Behavioral Scientist, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 8–14. Lui, F.T. (1985), ‘An Equilibrium Queuing Model of Bribery’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 93, pp. 760–81. Martin, A. (1971), Enterprise Denied: Origins of the Decline of American Railroads, 1897–1917, Columbia University Press, New York. Mauro, P. (1995), ‘Corruption and Growth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, pp. 681–712. Mautz, R.K. (1981), ‘Financial Reporting: Should Government Emulate Business?’, Journal of Accountancy, Vol. 152, No. 2. Mautz, R.K. (1988), ‘Monuments, Mistakes and Opportunities’, Accounting Horizons, Vol. 2, No. 2. Morris, S. (2000), ‘Issues in Infrastructure Development Today: The Interlinkages’, in S. Morris (ed.), India Infrastructure Report 2001: Issues in Regulation and Market Structure, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Murphy, K.M., A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny (1993), ‘Why is Rent-Seeking so Costly to Growth’, American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 2, pp. 409–514. Myrdal, G. (1968), Asian Drama, Vol. II, Random House, New York. Pallot, J. (1997), ‘Infrastructure Accounting for Local Authorities: Technical Management and Political Context’, Financial Accountability and Management, Vol. 16, No. 1, Spring. Robb, J.B. and A. Sugalski (2001), ‘The Deregulation that wasn’t’, McKinsey Quarterly, No. 3, available at http:// www.McKinseyQuarterly.com/ Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978), Corruption: A Study in Political Economy, Academic Press, New York. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1994), ‘Reducing Bribery in Public Sector’, in D.V. Trang (ed.), Corruption and Democracy: Political Institutions, Processes and Corruption in Transition States in East-Central Europe and in the Former Soviet Union, Budapest Institute for Constitutional and Legislative Policy. Rowles, T.R. (1992), ‘Financial Reporting of Infrastructure and Heritage Assets by Public Sector Entities’, Discussion Paper No. 17, Australian Accounting Research Foundation. Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny (1992), ‘Pervasive shortages under Socialism’, Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 23 No. 2, pp. 237–46. Shleifer, A. and R.W. Vishny (1993), ‘Corruption’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108, No. 3, pp. 599–617. Shleifer, A. and R.W. Vishny (1997), ‘A Survey of Corporate Governance’, Journal of Finance, Vol. 52, No. 2, pp. 737– 83. Stover, John F. (1961), American Railroads: The Chicago History of American Civilization, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Sunder, S. (1999), ‘A Theory of Accounting and Controls for Organizations Producing Public—Versus Private—Goods’, Inaugural Presidential Research Lecture at the Annual Meetings of the American Accounting Association, San Diego, 8 August. Tanzi, V. and H. Davoodi (1998), ‘Corruption, Public Investment, and Growth’, in H. Shibata and T. Ihori (eds), The Welfare State, Public Investment, and Growth, SpringerVerlag, Tokyo. Tarbell, I.M. (1904), The History of the Standard Oil Company, Macmillan, reprinted 1963, Peter Smith, Gloucester, Mass. Taylor, J. and P. VanDoren (2001), ‘California’s Electricity Crisis: What’s Going On, Who’s to Blame, and What to Do’, Policy Analysis, No. 406, 3 July, Cato Institute, available at http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa406.pdf. Tiebout, C. (1956), ‘A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 64, pp. 416–24. Tirole, J. (1996), ‘A Theory of Collective Reputations’, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 63, No. 1, pp. 1–22. Toynbee, Arnold J. (1956), A Study of History, Oxford University Press, London. Tullock, G. (1980), ‘Rent-seeking as a Negative Sum Game’, in J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison, and G. Tullock (eds), Towards a Theory of the Rent-seeking Society, Texas A&M University Press, College Station. Van Daniker, R. and V. Kwiatkowski (1986), ‘Infrastructure Assets: An Assessment of User Needs and Recommendations for Financial Reporting’, GASB. Varma, J.R. (2000), ‘Regulatory Dilemmas in Infrastructure Financing’, in S. Morris (ed.), India Infrastructure Report 2001: Issues in Regulation and Market Structure, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. Wade, R. (1997), ‘How Infrastructure Agencies Motivate Staff: Canal Irrigation in India and the Republic of Korea’, in A. Mody (ed.), Infrastructure Strategies in East Asia, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Walker, R.G., F.L. Clarke and G.W. Dean (2000), ‘Options for Infrastructure Reporting’, Abacus, Vol. 36, No. 2. Rural Infrastructure 187 7 RURAL INFRASTRUCTURE 7.1 ENDOWMENTS AND RURAL INFRASTRUCTURE: ISSUES TODAY1 Keshab Das The removal/reduction of poverty and the provision of basic civic amenities to the population, especially those living in rural areas, have been the most important goals in the Plan documents. This was stated as a primary objective by even the National Planning Committee, People’s Plan, and Bombay Plan prepared during the period prior to independence. The approach and agency for accelerating rural development have varied across Plans. Rural areas would have a high concentration of poverty given the existence of disguised unemployment in a big way in agriculture. Access to land, and ownership of land are the key to income differences since land is the major productive asset in rural areas. Rural areas may be more usefully viewed as concentration of poor resulting in little value for economic demand for infrastructural services. The fact remains that state interventions, despite their large scale of operations, never aimed at any basic structural changes in the agrarian society. What could have been the simplest and most effective way i.e. through land reform to eliminate poverty was never pursued despite the rhetoric. Governance and infrastructure are secondary to endowments. But without endowments, good governance is a contradiction in terms. The numerous programmes/schemes that included massive interventions such as the Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP), Mini-mum Needs Programme (MNP), and Public Distribution System (PDS) have, as both scholarly 1 Sincere thanks are due to Sebastian Morris for substantive comments on an earlier draft and constructive editing. Pragmatic comments by Rajiv Shekhar proved very useful. Thanks are also due to Dennis Rajkumar, Loraine Kennedy and Tara Nair for meaningful interventions. analyses and reports in the media establish, generally failed. Such failures have been attributed to serious deficiencies/ loopholes in design, access, and targeting. The ubiquitous scapegoat has invariably been identified as ‘poor implementation’—a catch-all expression for corruption, leakages, selection bias, paro-chialism, vested interests, and power politics. The government too has been doing its own evaluations; but beyond getting ritualistic studies conducted through external agencies, little or no corrective measures, based on their recommendations, have been pursued with effect. As it happens, more often than not, by the time the evaluation of a certain programme/scheme is nearly over, the next programme gets launched, afresh and without reference to possible lessons through a thorough evaluation of a previous programme. So far as the basic infrastructure for rural areas is concerned, there hardly seems any improvement despite reforms. Even during the post-reform period, say between 1993–4 and 2001–2, not only has the share of budgetary expenditure on all social services and poverty alleviation programmes declined from 2.08 to 1.87 per cent, but also the share of rural development in all social services and poverty alleviation programmes has fallen from about 32 to 25 per cent during the same period. PLANNING AND THE RURAL SECTOR It is impossible to ignore the rural sector whenever strategies of development are pursued. Indian planning has a history of intervening in and emphasizing and the problems of the rural sector. 188 India Infrastructure Report 2002 It was around the mid-1970s that the concept of basic minimum needs came into the policy frame, with an explicit acknowledgement of the worsening rural poverty situation and large scale unemployment. During the Sixth Plan, issues relating to basic infrastructure were sought to be addressed in a rather cohesive and more direct manner than before. The Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP) was introduced as a major strategy to create gainful employment through helping to generate a resource base at the household level and, ultimately, removing poverty. Despite a well spread out and adequately staffed rural development machinery with a supposedly strong bureaucratic, administrative, and training network, the results of the IRDP and related programmes were most unsatisfactory, with unbelievable stories of manipulation and misuse of funds being reported time and again. As the Draft Approach Paper to the Tenth Plan (p. 5) has surmised: the projects undertaken under the programme suffer from numerous defects including especially sub-critical investment levels; unviable projects; lack of technological and institutional capabilities in designing and executing projects utilising local resources and expertise; illiterate and unskilled beneficiaries with no experience in managing an enterprise; indifferent delivery of credit by banks (high transaction cost, complex procedure, corruption, one-time credit, poor recovery); overcrowding of lending in certain projects such as dairy; poor targeting and selection of non-poor; absence of linkage between different components of the IRDP; rising indebtedness; and scale of IRDP outstripped capacity of government and banks to absorb...Besides, the programme for upgrading skills, TRYSEM (Training of Rural Youth for Self Employment), was not dovetailed with IRDP. One discovered non-existent training centres and non-payment of stipend in some cases. The reasons for such implementation failures varied extensively. Whereas many scholars and policy observers blamed the failures on a variety of problems inherent in the design and delivery mechanism of the Programme (see, for instance, Rath 1985; Dreze 1990), some located the glitch in the system itself. That is to say, for the state to conduct the ‘passive revolution’, ‘irrational’ politics was taking advantage of ‘rational’ planning not only to further the interests of the dominant ruling classes but also to legitimize their hegemonic rule. This happened by mobilization of elements within the dominated groups and their accommodation (Chatterjee 1997: pp. 94–9; Byres 1997: pp. 71–2). With the government and bureaucracy coming under severe criticism for their laxity, mismanagement and general distancing from the concerned people, the hitherto inconspicuous so called non-governmental and voluntary organizations (NGOs, for short) were considered to be ‘closer’ to the people and could deliver effectively. Through the Seventh Plan document, the government formally acknowledged the importance of popular participation, especially in rural areas, for the successful execution of its programmes, and explicitly sought to engage NGOs in the implementation of the MNP and various anti-poverty programmes. Towards facilitating NGO’s involvement, especially since the mid-1980s, there has been both an increase and diversification of government funding made available to them. Grants to the NGOs are obtainable directly through the government as also parastatal bodies like the Council for Advancement of People’s Action and Rural Technology (CAPART), mainly for activities concerning infrastructure, both social and physical—for instance, to NGOs working in the areas of health care, drinking water, adult education, literacy, socio-economic welfare of women and children, rural housing, and forest development. With the growing proclivity towards economic liberalization and reforms, the state increasingly expected the NGOs not only to emulate its own agenda and pattern of development, but also to actually assume governmental role in rural development (Sen 1999: p. 344). A large number of NGOs did, in fact, undertake implementation of governmental programmes. The Eighth Plan, by which time the reforms process had formally begun, was clearer and keener than the previous Plan in stressing the critical role of NGOs in carrying out development programmes at the grass-roots. Despite the State’s proclaimed inclusion of NGOs in rural development programmes, the former’s attitude and treatment towards the latter, so far as micro level functional aspects are concerned, have come under much criticism. As one important study puts it, the State–NGO relationships have often been ‘characterized by the hostility of politicians, party workers, local elites, lower level bureaucrats, and lower level employees of the state towards NGO activity’ (Sen 1999: p. 353). CHRONIC RURAL POVERTY: THE BITTER REALITY It is well known that the achievement through planned development till almost the early 1960s, that is, during the Third Plan, was commendable, relative, to the growth rate during the colonial period. East Asian industrializing economies were able to achieve much higher rates of growth. Despite this, a high proportion of rural population remained below the poverty line; between 1960 and 1964, the poverty ratio remained between about 57 per cent and 54 per cent, accounting for over 202 million people. The growth rate of GDP, subsequently, hovered around an almost fatalistic and clearly ignominous 3 to 3.5 per cent per annum, reflecting the combined effect of not only a series of bad agricultural years, idle industrial capacity, and an unfavourable terms of trade against agriculture, but also Rural Infrastructure 189 Table 7.1.1 Dimensions of Poverty and Inequality in Rural India, 1973–2000 Year 1973–4 1977–8 1983 1987–8 1993–4 1999–2000 Poverty Ratio 56.4 53.1 45.7 39.1 37.3 27.1* 24.0** No. Of Poor (million) Poverty Gap Lorenz Ratio Index 261.3 264.3 252.0 231.9 244.0 16.56 15.73 12.32 9.11 8.45 0.27581 0.33861 0.29759 0.29826 0.28190 No. of Rural and Urban Poor (million) 321.3 328.9 322.9 307.1 320.3 * Based on 30 day recall; ** Based on 7 day recall. Source: Ninth Plan (1997–2002): Institutional Development at http://planningcommission.nic.in and Economic Survey 2000–2001 at http://www.nic.in. political instability arising from the decline and division of the monolith of the Congress party and the rise of regional contingent politics. Between the late 1960s and late 1970s, probably the most difficult period for Indian development, the populism of promise to eliminate poverty remained the ‘trump card’ of both the Congress (I) as well as the Janata Party, which came to power towards the end of the 1970s. With or without the slogan of ‘Garibi Hatao’, the proportion of rural poor hardly declined; in fact, the proportion had reached around 53 per cent, which implied that over 260 million persons remained below the poverty line even during much of the seventies (Table 7.1.1). The outcome was, unfortunately, not in keeping with the claims of the two parties. The early 1980s witnessed the return of the Congress party with redoubled vitality derived from a massive mandate. And with that the platitudes and programmes to abrogate poverty were invigorated. The percentage of rural population below the poverty line did climb down somewhat, but, not again, commensurate with the efforts and the hype. As Table 7.1.1 indicates, in 1983 the number of rural poor remained as high as 252 million even as the poverty ratio declined to about 46 per cent. With further reduction in the ratio to 39 per cent in 1987–8 and 37 per cent in 1993– 4, one could talk of a ‘secular’ decline in the incidence of poverty. Equally importantly, the Lorenz ratio, the most commonly used measure of inequality, for rural India has remained more or less stable. But this stability, especially for the recent years, have begun to be questioned, as ‘there is reason to believe that the measures of inequality based on the NSS consumption distribution may actually understate the true level of inequality in the country’ (Ninth Plan 1997–2002: Institutional Development, section on Growth Performance and Poverty, at http://planningcommission.nic.in). The total (both rural and urban) number of poor has remained at around a staggering 320 million virtually throughout the two decades spanning between 1973–4 and 1993–4. As per the NSS 55th round of survey, during 1999– 2000 the poverty ratio for rural India has been estimated at about 27 per cent (based on 30 day recall) or at 24 per cent (based on 7 day recall). The results of this specific survey round, stated to have used a different/innovative methodology, are still being debated as to their comparability with results of the previous ones. Meanwhile, the latest available World Bank data shows a clear rise in the incidence of poverty in India—with a GNP per capita of US$440 in 1999, India continues to have the highest concentration of poverty, with more than 360 million people (about 36 per cent of its total population) living below the official poverty line. Using an international poverty line, India is estimated to have 40 per cent of the world’s poor (Das 2001). After a decade of economic reforms, it is fairly obvious that the grand neo-liberal proposition that growth shall trickle down to the poor and elevate their levels of living has not been realized. In a detailed analysis of poverty statistics by S.P. Gupta (as reported in Das 2001), it has been established that the 1990s have hardly done anything for the poor in India, the rural poor, particularly. In fact, data suggest that during the reforms period not only was there no secular decline in poverty but actually there was an addition of 70 million people to the poverty category between 1989–90 and 1997. Importantly, during the 1980s, when between 1983 and 1990–1 the incidence of poverty declined by 3.1 per cent per annum, the GDP growth per annum was 5.6 per cent. Almost as a reversal of the situation, between 1990–1 and 1997 the incidence of poverty increased by 1 per cent annually, although the GDP growth had accelerated during the same period (Not shown in the table). The focus of the reform have been away from poverty alleviation programmes, or for the rural sector particularly, or even agriculture, the backbone of the Indian rural economy. Plan outlays for rural development hardly rose during the 1990s. The ‘unmistakable’ urban–industrial bias 190 India Infrastructure Report 2002 of the reforms strategies have further accentuated rural– urban disparities in income (Bhaduri and Nayyar 1996: p. 111; Nagaraj 2000: p. 2838). Moreover, the differences between per capita income of the rich and poor states have been on the rise during the reform period. As Jha (2001: p. 8) points out, ‘regional inequality in the incidence of rural poverty is increasing over time, particularly since the reforms began. Thus not only are the poorest of the poor getting ignored, they are also getting regionally concentrated’. It was more by design and less by default that the economic opportunities for the rural poor, who are anyway disadvantaged by high incidence of illiteracy, ill health, and constricted access to basic physical infrastructure, failed to be created in a manner that would have energized the rural economy. This underscores the fact that growth of GDP per se does not automatically ‘pull up’ people into gainful employment or root out chronic and abject rural poverty (Dreze and Sen 1995; Guhan 1995; Dev and Ranade 1999).2 remain innumerable villages (not to mention their many habitations) that lack even the most basic facilities. It will be naive to state that there is no need for the same. But why did not the private capital flow to these regions? It is instructive to take note of the following from the ‘Draft Approach Paper: Tenth Five Year Plan 2002–2007’ (at http:/ /planningcommission.nic.in): ‘There are many areas, e.g. the social sectors, where its (the government’s) role will clearly have to increase. There are other areas, e.g. infrastructure development, where gaps are large and private sector cannot be expected to step in significantly. In these areas the role of government may have to be restructured. It will have to increase in some areas of infrastructure development which are unlikely to attract private investment e.g. rural infrastructure and road development’ (Chapter 1, p. 2, emphasis added). STATE Probably one of the most dismal records that India has relates to sanitation, especially in rural areas. As per the Census of India 1991, it is truly a shame that a staggering 91 per cent of households in Indian villages did not have toilet facilities! As may be seen from Table 7.1.2, even at the turn of the new millennium and almost a decade since the reforms began, a meagre 9 per cent of rural population had been covered by some form of sanitation. This is an infrastructure of utmost urgency, and no time should be wasted over such issues as whether there exists a demand for it, whether class and caste factors prevail upon the decision to possess and use such facilities, etc.3 In a country where the rural infant mortality rate has remained OR MARKET? It may be pertinent to note that in order to counter criticism of the government’s apathy towards social sectors during the first five years of the reforms process (this was amply reflected through the pattern and quantum of Plan expenditure on this sector and also the low ratio of this expenditure to the GDP at current prices), during 1996–7 an all-out effort was made to increase investment in social sectors towards ‘achieving distributive justice’. As most of these sectors came under the domain of the State List, a conference of chief ministers on Basic Minimum Services, held in July 1996, recommended the adoption of a set of objectives so as to strive towards their attainment by 2000. For our present purpose, these objectives included, 100 per cent coverage of provision of safe drinking water in rural areas, provision of Public Housing Assistance to all shelterless poor families, and telecom connectivity to all unconnected villages and habitations. In addition to continuing all centrally sponsored schemes relating to the aforesaid basic minimum services, the states were to raise their annual entitlement by 15–20 per cent annually. Further, it endorsed that ‘the funds allocated for these Basic Minimum Services in the States’ and Central Plans should not be diverted’ (Economic Survey 1997 at http://www.nic.in/indiabudget/es97/chap10.htm, pp. 1–2). By 2001, the claims about fufilling all the gaps in infrastructure for the rural poor have, literally, fallen by the wayside. Not only has rural poverty persisted but there 2 But growth at very high rates, as in East Asia, have led to significant increase in incomes of all sections and this growth was itself contigent on endowment for all (ed.). SANITATION FACILITIES Table 7.1.2 Sanitation Facilites in Rural India, 1985–99 (Percentages) Year 1985 1990 1995 1998 1999 Population covered 0.7 2.4 3.6* 8.1* 9.0* * With government initiative only. Authentic data on coverage through private initiative not known. Percentage coverage based on population in current year to corresponding 1991 Census. Source: Government of India, Economic Survey 2000–1, p. 208. 3 Indeed, the external effects of toilets are very large and positive, to such an extent that it would be easy to show that those who can afford would be willing to subsidize those who cannot, in the interest of health and well being. Rural Infrastructure 191 as high as 82 per thousand live births (1993 figure based on the Sample Registration Survey prepared by the Registrar General of India) and a major cause of mortality is diarrhoeal diseases (occurring mostly due to oral faecal infection), sanitation remains crucial. It is rather unfortunate that while Indian scholars and planners have debated for decades over rural poverty and its correlates, one hardly comes across a study that has undertaken careful analysis of the pathetic perfomance in rural sanitation (this was despite valuable data being made available in the National Sample Survey Organisation (NSSO), Census, and other rural development data sources). Notwithstanding the dearth of studies in this field, especially relating to demand for and willingness to pay in the rural Indian context, it will be worthwhile to consider the provision of household level facilities, rather than common toilets. In the case of common toilet arrangements in urban and semi-urban areas, mostly through the very successful Sulabh International efforts, the facility is mainly used by a non-resident and transient population. However, in rural areas, at a residential level, such a concept will be difficult to operationalize. In fact, maintenance on a regular basis will remain the most ticklish issue to handle. In an extensive field survey based study (Das and Visaria 1998) concerning evaluation of an intervention under the Integrated Rural Sanitation Programme conducted in north Gujarat, it was learnt that most beneficiary households reported the use of latrine facility by all members of the household. What is interesting to note, however, is that among the reasons given for the use of the facility, hygienic considerations did not receive prime attention. Whereas this could be reflective of laxity in efforts at IEC (information, education and communication), the clear preference for the facility indicates presumably that once a facility is created its advantages begin to be recognized and it gets used, providing an instance of hardware-induced change in sanitation practices. The provision of latrines under the Integrated Rural Sanitation Programme to some households had generated a high demand among the non-beneficiaries to have the latrines. Nearly 90 per cent of those surveyed indicated their willingness to have latrines constructed.