Untitled - European Journal of Economic and Political Studies
Transcription
Untitled - European Journal of Economic and Political Studies
European Journal of Economic and Political Studies Vol: 8 No: 1 Summer 2015 Contents Can Management Practices Make a Difference? Nonprofit Organization Financial Performance during Times of Economic Stress Qian Hu, Naim Kapucu ......................................................................................... 1 A Critical Review of Theoretical Perspectives on Emerging Economy Multinationals Yüksel Ayden ........................................................................................................ 19 Empowerment and Trust as Mediators of the Relationship between Transformational Leadership and Organizational Effectiveness Agron Hoxha ......................................................................................................... 43 The ‘Common Sense’ of Austerity in Europe’s Historic Bloc: A Gramscian Analysis Ben Luongo ........................................................................................................... 61 Islam and Foreign Policy: The Case of Qatar Turan Kayaoğlu .................................................................................................... 93 European Journal of Economic and Political Studies 8 (2015) 1-18 Can Management Practices Make a Difference? Nonprofit Organization Financial Performance during Times of Economic Stress Qian HU*, Naim KAPUCU School of Public Administration, University of Central Florida, United States Abstract The economic crisis presented unprecedented challenges to nonprofit organizations to sustain their services. In this study, we examined both financial and management factors that influence the financial performance of nonprofit organizations during times of economic stress. In particular, we investigated whether strategic planning and plan implementation, revenue diversification, and board involvement help nonprofit organizations deal with financial uncertainty and strengthen financial performance. Despite the negative impacts that the economic downturn had on nonprofit organizations, we found that the implementation of strategic plans can help nonprofit organizations reduce financial vulnerability. Our findings call attention to key management factors that influence the financial performance of nonprofit organizations. Key Words: Financial Performance, Strategic Planning, Plan Implementation JEL Classification: L10, L25, L30, H12. * Corresponding author. Tel: +1 (407) 823 3340 E-mail addresses: [email protected] (Q. Hu), [email protected] (N. Kapucu). Page | 1 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 1. Introduction The nonprofit sector has become a crucial provider of human and social services as well as a driving economic force in the United States. During the economic turbulence following the global financial crisis of 2008, the nonprofit sector faced unprecedented challenges of pursuing sustainable development. In this study, we examined factors that influence nonprofit organizations’ financial performance in times of economic crisis. Previous research has focused on factors such as funding sources, revenue diversification, board size, board engagement, organizational attributes, and environmental factors (Besel, Williams, & Klak, 2011; Bowman, 2011; Carroll & Stater, 2009; Graddy & Wang, 2009; Hodge & Piccolo, 2005; Ritchie & Kolodinsky, 2003; Trussel, 2002; Tuckman & Chang, 1991). To understand why nonprofit organizations performed better or worse during the economic downturn, we not only included financial factors but also considered the impacts of management factors, such as the use of strategic planning, strategic plan implementation, and board commitment (Boyne & Walker, 2004; Bryson, 2011; Moore, 2000; Mosley, Maronick, & Katz, 2012; Poister, Pitts, & Edwards, 2010). We addressed two questions in particular: What factors influence financial performance of nonprofit organizations during times of economic stress? Can strategic planning and plan implementation help nonprofit organizations tackle financial uncertainty and strengthen financial performance? We examined the financial performance of nonprofit organizations in Central Florida during the economic downturn starting in early 2008. Organizational attributes, management data, and financial data were obtained from the Central Florida Foundation (CFF). Findings from this study can inform both researchers and nonprofit managers about how to apply strategies to enhance financial performance in times of financial uncertainty. Unlike other studies focusing on revenue factors, this study showed that strategic plan implementation may help organizations perform better financially during economic crises. Our findings also call increased attention to management practices that impact the financial performance of nonprofit organizations. 2. Literature Review Facing financial uncertainty, some nonprofit organizations may demonstrate great financial sustainability, whereas others are relatively less stable financially. This section first discusses the measures of financial performance of nonprofit organizations and then reviews factors that influence financial performance of nonprofit organizations, especially during times of financial stress. These key factors include funding sources and revenue diversification, board size and board Page | 2 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 involvement, strategic planning and implementation, organization size, and environmental factors. 2.1. Nonprofit Organization Financial Performance Many means are available for measuring the financial performance of nonprofit organizations are numerous, but few are widely agreed on (Berman, 1998; Martin & Kettner, 2010; Ritchie & Kolodinsky, 2003). Tuckman and Chang (1991) called for research studying “financial vulnerability” of nonprofits, defining nonprofits as financially vulnerable if they were likely to reduce service provisions in the face of financial stress. They further proposed four operational criteria to evaluate financial vulnerability: inadequate equity balances, revenue concentration, low administrative costs, and low or negative operating margins (pp.451-453). Greenlee and Trussel (2000) added a time dimension to the definition of financial vulnerability and considered nonprofits organizations to be financially vulnerable if they reduced program expenditures for three consecutive years. Trussel (2002) further redefined financial vulnerability and added that organizations showing a 20% decrease in fund balances over three years are to be considered financial vulnerable, according to such indicators as debt ratio, revenue concentration, and surplus margin. In another study, Trussel, Greenlee, and Brady (2002) proposed a financial vulnerability index based on a regression analysis of five indicators: debt ratio, revenue concentration, surplus margin, administrative cost ratio, and size (natural log of total assets). A financial vulnerability index score higher than 0.2 demonstrates the financial vulnerability of the nonprofit organization (Trussel et al., 2002). In empirical studies of the financial performance of nonprofits, the financial vulnerability index proposed by Trussel et al. has been frequently applied, tested, and revised (e.g., Hodge & Piccolo, 2005). Different from the index approach, other scholars broke down financial performance measures into different subcategories. For instance, Ritchie and Kolodinsky (2003) interviewed key informants of university foundations and conducted factor analysis of the six financial measures from the IRS form 990. They identified three performance categories: fund-raising efficiency, measured by the ratio of direct public support to fund-raising expenses and the ratio of total revenue to fund-raising expenses; public support, measured by total contributions divided by total revenue and direct public support divided by total assets; and fiscal performance, measured by the ratio of total revenue to total expenses and the ratio of total contributions to total expenses. Their approach recommends using multiple measures to evaluate various aspects of nonprofit financial performance. Page | 3 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 Bowman (2011) critiqued the static view of the financial status of nonprofit organizations and maintained that a time dimension needs to be added to the model measuring financial capacity and financial sustainability. He argued that nonprofits have both the short-term goal of building resilience toward environmental uncertainty and the long-term objective of sustaining or expanding services. Hence, he proposed two sets of measures to evaluate financial capacity and financial sustainability according to those two objectives. With the long-term goal of sustaining or expanding services, financial capacity is measured by equity ratio, and financial sustainability is measured by return on assets. With the shortterm goal of developing resilience toward financial stress, financial capacity can be measured by “Months of Spending (MS) before running out of expendable resources,” and financial sustainability can be measured by “the change in the numerator of Months of Spending divided by spending on operations” (p.43). 2.2. Funding Source and Revenue Diversification Funding sources and diversification of fund sources can influence nonprofit organizations’ financial performance. Heavy reliance on government revenue can have adverse effects on service delivery strategies (Besel et al., 2011). Nonprofit organizations that rely mostly on such contributions may be at risk of resource dependency during times of economic stress (Carroll & Stater, 2009; Herman, Head, Jackson, & Fogarty, 2004). Hodge and Piccolo (2005) found that privately funded nonprofit agencies were less susceptible to economic shock than nonprofit organizations funded by government or other commercial agencies. Many nonprofits may not be able to dramatically change the primary source of their revenues; however, they may be able to diversify their portfolios. Greenlee (2002) noted that revenue diversification can reduce net asset loss as well as the likelihood of cutting off programs or services. On the contrary, revenue concentration can increase the risk of revenue decline (Herman et al., 2004; Keating et al., 2005). By diversifying revenue through “equalizing reliance on earned income, investments, and contributions,” nonprofit organizations can reduce their revenue volatility (Carroll & Stater, 2009, p. 962). By examining longitudinal data on public charities between 1991 and 2003, Carroll and Stater (2008) found that revenue diversification is an effective strategy to help organizations obtain stable revenues and decrease revenue volatility. This strategy is especially important when nonprofits face financial uncertainty. To measure the level of revenue diversification of nonprofit organizations, we have adopted the widely used Hirscheman-Herfindal index (Carroll & Stater, 2009). The sources of revenue are grouped into four categories: (1) government grants; (2) donations that include direct and indirect public support and private gifts, as well Page | 4 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 as gross income from special events; (3) earned income, including program revenue, dues, and other earned income; and (4) investment income, consisting of interest, securities, and other investment income (Calabrese, 2013; Yan, Denison & Butler, 2009). Ri represents the proportion of each category of revenue to the total revenue. This revenue diversification index measures the extent to which nonprofit revenues are evenly distributed among the four categories of revenue sources. The higher the value, the greater level of revenue diversification the nonprofit organization has. Assuming that diverse revenue sources can help nonprofit organizations reduce financial volatility, we hypothesized that revenue diversification can help improve the financial performance of nonprofits. Revenue Diversification Index = 1− 4 𝑅2 𝑖=1 𝑖 0.75 Hypothesis 1: Revenue diversification can improve the financial performance of nonprofits during times of economic stress. 2.3. Board Size and Involvement Managing the financial health of nonprofits is a major part of the board’s formal responsibilities (Besel et al., 2011; Bradshaw, Murray, & Wolpin, 1992; Zimmerman & Stevens, 2008). Board members can play a prominent role in fund development due to their strong connections with external environments (Brown & Guo, 2010). Board commitment and involvement, board composition and structure, and relationships between executives and boards may influence the strategies that nonprofit organizations use to deal with financial uncertainty and their financial performance. Strong, supportive relationships between the executive and the board tend to produce more effective organizations (Balser & McClusky, 2005). Committed board members were reported to be more involved in the organization and were perceived to be engaged and were valued by the executive director of nonprofit organizations (Preston & Brown, 2004). The increased use of board involvement techniques has been shown to produce lower levels of financial vulnerability (Hodge & Piccolo, 2005). Board commitment can be measured by board meeting attendance at required meetings, participation (e.g., length of service on the board, service on committees, hours donated to the organization), and financial donations (Preston & Brown, 2004). Hence, we hypothesize that there is a positive relationship between board involvement and the financial performance of nonprofit organizations. Hypothesis 2: Board involvement positively correlates with the financial performance of nonprofits during times of economic stress. Page | 5 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 2.4. Strategic Planning and Plan Implementation Strategic planning can influence the financial performance and vulnerability of nonprofits. According to Bryson (2011), strategic planning is “a deliberative, disciplined approach to producing fundamental decisions and actions that shape and guide what an organization (or other entity) is, what it does, and why” (pp.78). Strategic planning has potential for advancing both social and financial performance (Siciliano, 2006), and they allow organizations to take proactive measures, explore collaboration opportunities for joint programs, and carry out new programs (Mosley et al., 2012). Many nonprofits adopt strategic planning in their management practices to increase potential funding opportunities and to satisfy the expectations of potential funders (Crittenden & Crittenden, 2000). Strategic planning may help nonprofits think strategically, diversify revenue sources, and improve decision making and performance (Bryson & Roering, 1988; Jimenez, 2013; McHatton, Bradshaw, Gallagher, & Reeves, 2011; Stone, Bigelow, & Crittenden, 1999). Facing financial uncertainty, nonprofit organizations can use adaptive or reactive strategies such as adding new programs, cutting off existing programs or staff, building or expanding a joint program through collaboration, increasing earned income, or starting or increasing involvement in advocacy (Mosley et al., 2012). Yet, the relationship between strategic planning and financial performance of nonprofit organizations is not always straightforward, and research examining the impact of strategic planning on organizational performance remains limited and inconclusive (Poister, Pitts, & Edwards, 2010). Nonprofit organizations often utilize formal strategic planning because they are required by funders to do so (Stone et al., 1999). Poister and Streib (2005) found that while nearly 44% of the municipal governments that they surveyed had adopted strategic planning, only 33% of the sample cities had linked their budgets with strategic goals, and only 22% had utilized performance measurement. In a study on the impact of strategic planning on city fiscal performance, Jimenez (2013) did not find significantly positive impacts of strategic planning on city fiscal status. He further noted that some cities may adopt strategic planning as a symbolic action to satisfy key stakeholders. To make strategic planning more useful, he suggested that performance management systems, clear goals and objectives, and guidance are important for implementing strategic plans. Having a strategic plan does not necessarily lead to improved financial performance of nonprofits; it is the actual plan implementation that may contribute to healthier financial conditions. Hypothesis 3: Plan implementation may help reduce the financial vulnerability of nonprofits. Page | 6 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 2.5. Dependence on External Sources and Organizational Size The economic crisis of 2008 has exerted great pressure on the growth of nonprofit organizations (Besel et al., 2011; Mosley et al., 2012). Heavy reliance on government grants or external donations may make nonprofit organizations more vulnerable to external financial uncertainty (Besel et al., 2011). In addition, the size of a nonprofit may affect its financial performance and vulnerability, as shown in Figure 1. A study by Mosley et al. (2012) examined structural, managerial, and financial characteristics to see how they were related to adaptive tactics used by nonprofit organizations faced with financial uncertainty. Small nonprofit organizations are limited in how they can proactively respond to financial hardship (Greenlee & Trussel, 2000; Mosley et al., 2012; Siciliano, 2006). Hence, we developed the following two hypotheses. Hypothesis 4: External financial conditions since 2008 have had a negative impact on the financial performance of nonprofits. Hypothesis 5: Large organizations are more likely to have better financial performance during times of economic uncertainty. Economic Crisis Financial Status Board: Size Involvement Strategic Planning & Plan Implementation Financial Performance Other Factors: Organization Size Figure 1. Factors Impacting Nonprofit Financial Performance during Times of Economic Stress Page | 7 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 3. Method Data for this study were provided by the Central Florida Foundation (CFF). The CFF, established in 1994, is a nonprofit foundation that manages and invests “nearly 400 charitable funds established by generous individuals, families and corporations” to serve the financial needs of nonprofit organizations in Central Florida (CFF, 2014). To better understand community issues and to utilize and allocate resources, the CFF built a knowledge database to collect information about nonprofit organizations located in Central Florida. Compared with other large national databases, the CFF knowledge database has its own strengths: The knowledge database has collected rich data about local nonprofits and has updated the data regularly. It includes not only organizational financial data and organizational attributes data, such as age and service area, but also management and governance data. Furthermore, the data, especially financial data, have been carefully reviewed and validated by the professional staff at CFF. Hence, the accuracy and validity of data have been improved than the self-reported survey data. This is different from the National Center for Charitable Statistics data that were collected from the self-reported Internal Revenue Service Form 990 and are mainly financial data (Lampkin & Boris, 2002). To understand the financial performance of nonprofits during the economic downturn, we compiled the financial data of nonprofits in Central Florida between fiscal year 2008 and fiscal year 2011. Due to the difficulty of collecting financial data from nonprofit organizations—especially from small nonprofit organizations—these data are the most recent financial data available for analysis after the 2008 financial crisis. Management data, organizational attributes, board size, and board involvement data for 2010 were merged with the financial data. The merged dataset included 194 nonprofit organizations. However, because data for certain variables were missing across all 194 organizations, we decided to include 110 nonprofit organizations for the following statistical analysis. As shown in Table 1, the sample includes a wide range of nonprofit organizations with varying sizes, funding structures, and budgets. Page | 8 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 Table 1. Descriptive Statistics of Organizations Funding Structure (2010) Government Grants Private Contributions and Donations Program Revenue Investment Income Total Expenses $0 - $100,000 $100,001 – $500,000 $500,001 – $1,000,000 $1,000,001 - $5,000,000 Over $5,000,000 Board Size (number of members) 5-10 11-20 21-30 Over 30 Staff size (# of full-time employees) 1-5 6-15 16-25 26-50 Over 50 Valid N (Listwise) = 110 Average percentage of total revenue 17.1 % 55.1 % 28.9 % 1.6 % Number (Percentage) 33 (17.6 %) 38 (20.2 %) 26 (13.8 %) 55 (29.3 %) 37 (19.1 %) Number (Percentage) 48 (35 %) 56 (40.9 %) 15 (10.9 %) 18 (13.1 %) Number (Percentage) 46 (41.4 %) 24 (21.6 %) 13 (11.7 %) 14 (12.6 %) 14 (12.6 %) 3.1. Key Variables In this study, we measured the key dependent variable—the financial performance of nonprofits—by calculating the change from 2010 to 2011 in the deficit-to-expenditure ratio. Nonprofit organizations in Central Florida experienced the greatest decreases in total revenues, total assets, and total expenditures between the fiscal years 2010 and 2011. Examining the financial performance of nonprofit organizations within these two years captured a snapshot of how nonprofit organizations reacted to the external financial stress. Moreover, using the ratio difference helped reduce the potential “serial correlation” issue. A positive ratio change indicated that the nonprofit organization under consideration had more deficits in relation to its expenditures. In addition, we calculated other financial health indices for each organization, including debt ratio, revenue diversification, administration cost to total revenue Page | 9 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 ratio, and margin, as suggested by previous research (Trussel, 2002). In addition, the change in the expenditure-to-revenue ratio from 2008 to 2010 was used as a measure of the past fiscal conditions (Jimenez, 2013). The change in the nonprofits’ dependence on government grants and donations from 2008 and 2010 were also included to measure their revenue source change. Total assets in 2008 and 2010 was used as a measure of organization size. One of the key independent variables is the presence of a formal strategic plan. Nonprofit organizations in Central Florida were expected to conduct strategic planning by potential funders, including the Central Florida Foundation. Another related variable was the plan implementation index, which measures whether performance evaluation was part of the management practice and whether supported plans were developed, such as succession plans, fund-raising plans, and policy procedure plans. Board size was measured by the total number of board members, board engagement was measured by the meeting attendance rate, and board commitment was measured by the percentage of board members who made monetary contributions to the organization. 3.2. Analysis and Two-Stage Least Squares Models Plan implementation index variables may cause endogenous issues as the plan implementation might also be influenced by fiscal conditions of nonprofits. We applied the two-stage least squares model is to analyze the impact of management and financial factors on the financial performance of nonprofit organizations. In the first stage, the 2010 plan implementation index was the dependent variable; the explanatory variables included the organizations’ previous financial conditions, the board variables, and the presence of formal strategic plans.In the second stage, the predicted values of the plan implementation index were used as an instrument to replace the original plan implement index to calculate the exogenous effects of plan implementation on the financial performance of nonprofits. Stage 1 model. Plan implementation index2010 = a + b1 Total assets2008 (log) + b2 (Change in expenditure revenue ratio2008-2010) + b3 Formal strategic plan2010 + b4 Board size + b5 Board meeting attendance rate + b6 Board contribution rate + b7 Dependence on government grants + b8 Dependence on donations + b9 (Change in dependence on government grants2008-2010) + b10(Change in dependence on donations2008-2010). Stage 2 model. Change in deficit to expenditure ratio2010-2011 = a + b1 Formal strategic plan2010 + b2 Plan implementation Index (Predicted from model 1) + b3 Board meeting attendance rate + b4 Total assets2010 (log) + b5 Administrative cost Page | 10 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 to total revenue ratio2010 + b6 (Change in the expenditure to revenue ratio2008-2010) + b7 (Change in dependence on government grants2008-2010) + b8 (Change in dependence on donations2008-2010) + b9 Revenue Diversification2010. 4. Findings and Discussion In the following section, we first present descriptive attributes of the local nonprofit organizations in Central Florida. As Table 2 depicts, approximately half of the organizations in the sample had strategic plans, nearly 40% of the nonprofits in the sample were developing strategic plans, and almost 10% of the nonprofits did not have strategic plans. The average value for the plan implementation index was 2.68. The majority of board members made monetary contributions to the organization. The nonprofit has an average number of 17 board members. The meeting attendance rate is nearly 72 percent. Table 2. Descriptive Statistics of Key Variables Financial Measures Deficit to total expenditure ratio in 2011 Deficit to total expenditure ration in 2010 Deficit to total expenditure ratio change from 2010 to 2011 Program expenditure to total revenue ratio Expenditure to revenue ratio change from 2008 to 2010 Debt ratio Revenue Diversification Margin Administrative Costs Ratio Management Practice Formal Strategic Plan Yes (%) No (%) Plan Implementation Index Board Involvement (% of meeting attendance) Board Size (number of members) Board Commitment (% of contributions) Valid N (Listwise) = 110 Mean -0.153 -0.070 0.069 S.D. 0.204 0.331 0.389 0.801 -0.031 0.282 0.311 0.066 0.339 0.012 0.153 0.155 0.341 0.288 0.204 56 (50.9%) 54 (49.1%) 2.68 71.6% 17.2 75.6% 1.34 12.86% 15.4 33.9% Compared with measures from 2008, when the financial crisis occurred, total revenues, total expenditures and total assets, program expenditures, and fundraising expenditures have decreased over the past four years (see Figure 2), with the fiscal year 2010-2011 witnessing the greatest decreases across these measures of financial health. Page | 11 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 7.00 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0.00 2008 2009 2010 2011 Total Revenue Total Expenditure Total Assets Total Liabilities Program Expenditure Fundraising Expenditure Figure 2. Key Variables between 2008-2011 * All numbers are in millions. As Table 3 shows, we did not find statistically significant support for the assumed negative relationships between nonprofits’ revenue diversification index and deficit ratio change and neither for the negative correlation between nonprofit organizations’ board involvement and deficit ratio change from 2010 to 2011. Therefore, hypotheses 1 and 2 were not supported by this study. The coefficients were not statistically significant, and the signs were different from the expected negative signs. The relationship between revenue diversification and the financial performance of nonprofits deserves more research. Recent research on this topic suggests that researchers need to delve into the “compositional change in the portfolio” when examining the impact of revenue diversification on financial performance (Mayer et al., 2014, p.374). Or, this positive relationship could have resulted from the proactive measures taken by large risk-taking organizations with active and dedicated board members. Our findings could also have been influenced by the limitation of the dependent variable, which is the deficit ratio change within two years. The deficit ratio change would be a more robust measure if we could have collected data representing a longer period of time. Page | 12 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 Table 3. Two staged Least Square Model Variables Management Variables Strategic plan (Yes or no) Plan implementation Index Board meeting attendance rate Financial Variables Total assets (log) in 2010 Administrative cost to total revenue ratio 2008 – 2010 change in the expenditure to revenue ratio 2008 – 2010 change in dependence on government grants 2008 – 2010 change in dependence on donations Revenue Diversification N R2 Adjusted R2 Coef. (B) St. Error 0.454 -0.347* 0.002 0.258 0.204 0.004 0.080 -0.067 0.552** 0.056 0.727 0.191 -0.357 0.362 -0.042 0.369 0.219 89 0.193 0.102 0.329 - We conducted Durbin-Wu-Hausman (DWH) test to examine whether the assumed endogenous regressor in the model—plan implementation index—is in fact endogenous. The Durbin-WuHausman chi-square (1) is 8.17 and is statistically significant with a p value smaller than .05. Therefore, we reject the null hypothesis that the variable of plan implementation index is exogenous and hold the assumption of endogeneity. - Significance at *: 5%, **: 1%. Hypothesis 3, however, was supported. As shown in Table 3, the plan implementation index was found to be negatively correlated with the deficit ratio change. The higher the implementation index, the smaller the deficit ratio increase, indicating that plan implementation may help nonprofit organizations envision potential opportunities and overcome financial uncertainty by developing and implementing various strategies to sustain or even expand existing programs. Hence, plan implementation may contribute to the overall financial health of nonprofits. Having a strategic plan does not necessarily lead to better financial performance, as many nonprofits decide to formulate a strategic plan simply because of external pressure from donors or other stakeholders. Once they have developed their strategic plans, they may not implement them in their management practice. It is important, therefore, to evaluate whether nonprofit organizations integrate strategic thinking and strategic planning in their management systems. As previous research (LeRoux & Wright, 2010) suggested, Page | 13 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 the use of specific measures may improve the implementation of strategies in nonprofit organizations. Hypothesis 4 was also supported, suggesting that the economic crisis has quickly worsened the financial performance of nonprofits. There is a strong positive relationship between the expenditure-to-revenue ratio change from 2008 to 2010 and the deficit ratio change from 2010 to 2011. Previous years’ higher expenditure ratios will further contribute to the deficit ratio accumulatively in the following years. Hypothesis 5 was not supported, which suggests a negative relationship between total assets and the deficit ratio change. In fact, large organizations with higher total assets seemed to have higher deficit ratio changes between 2010 and 2011. The sign between organizational size (measured by total assets) and deficit ratio change is also positive. Organizations that have large assets may decide to take more proactive measures to ensure regular operation despite economic uncertainty. 5. Conclusion In this study, we examined the financial status of nonprofit organizations in Central Florida and the factors that can influence the financial performance of nonprofit organizations in general. Besides the financial factors that have been extensively examined in existing literature, this study focused on the impact of management practices on financial performance, including strategic plans, plan implementation, and board involvement. This study contributes to exiting research by calling increased scholarly attention to management practices when examining the financial performance of nonprofits. The financial crisis of 2008 worsened nonprofit organizations’ financial conditions. On average, nonprofit organizations in Central Florida have decreased their program and fund-raising expenditures. Total revenue and total assets have also decreased. However, many nonprofit organizations have stayed in a financially sustainable state; so, more attention ought to be directed to finding out why some organizations can still grow in spite of financial stress. We found that plan implementation, not necessarily the plan itself, can have a positive influence on the financial performance of nonprofit organizations. Many nonprofit organizations may have strategic plans because they need to meet the requirements of existing stakeholders or potential funders. Having a strategic plan, however, does not automatically translate into better financial performance. Both the nonprofit managers and the funding organizations need to track carefully how the plan has been used in their management practices and whether strategic planning has been closely linked with other management areas, Page | 14 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 such as budgeting and performance management. We did not find revenue diversification to be a significant predictor of the financial performance of nonprofit organizations. Facing an economic downturn, organizations that are more confident in their revenue sources may take active measures to continue providing their services, and large organizations are more likely to spend more money to sustain existing programs. This study has some limitations.Here, we examined the financial performance of nonprofit organizations in a local region in Florida, but a larger-scale study may help improve the generalizability of the research findings. Moreover, collecting data on the deficit ratio change for a longer period of time may help improve the robustness of the measure. Future research may consider including qualitative interviews of select nonprofit organizations in the region to further delve into their management practices. In-depth interviews can allow researchers to understand what factors differentiate high-performing nonprofits from lowperforming nonprofits not only in their financial management but also in many other management areas. References Balser, D., and McClusky, J. (2005). Managing Stakeholder Relationships and Nonprofit Organization Effectiveness. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 15 (3), 295-315. Berman, E.M. (1998). Productivity in Public and Nonprofit Organizations: Strategies and Techniques. Los Angeles, CA: Sage. Besel, K., Williams, C.L., and Klak, J. (2011). Nonprofit Sustainability during Times of Uncertainty. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 22 (1), 53-65. Bowman, W. (2011). Financial Capacity and Sustainability of Ordinary Nonprofits. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 22 (1), 37-51. Boyne, G.A., and Walker, R.M. (2004). Strategy Content and Public Service Organizations. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 14 (2), 231-252. Bradshaw, P., Murray, V., and Wolpin, J. (1992). Do Nonprofit Boards Make a Difference? An Exploration of the Relationships among Board Structure, Process, and Effectiveness. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 21 (3), 227-249. Brown, W.A., and Guo, C. (2010). Exploring the Key Roles for Nonprofit Boards. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 39 (3), 536-546. Page | 15 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 Bryson, J.M. (2011). Strategic Planning for Public and Nonprofit Organizations. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass. Bryson, J.M., and Roering, W.D. (1988). Initiation of Strategic Planning by Governments. Public Administration Review, 995-1004. Calabrese, T. (2013). Running on Empty: The Operating Reserves of U.S. Nonprofit Organizations. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 23 (3), 281-302. Carroll, D.A., and Stater, K.J. (2009). Revenue Diversification in Nonprofit Organizations: Does it Lead to Financial Stability. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 19 (4), 947-966. CFF. (2015). Central Florida Foundation. About the Foundation. Retrieved from cffound.org/explore/about_cff/ Crittenden, W.F., and Crittenden, V.L. (2000). Relationships between Organizational Characteristics and Strategic Planning Processes in Nonprofit Organizations. Journal of Managerial Issues, 12 (2), 150-168. Graddy, E., and Wang, L. (2009). Community Foundation Development and Social Capital. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 38 (3), 392-412. Greenlee, J. (2002). Revisiting the Prediction of Financial Vulnerability. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 13 (1), 17-31. Greenlee, J.S., and Trussel, J.M. (2000). Predicting the Financial Vulnerability of Charitable Organizations. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 11 (2), 199-210. Herman, M.L., Head, G.L., Jackson, P.M., and Fogarty, T.E. (2004). Managing Risk in Nonprofit Organizations. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley. Hodge, M.M., and Piccolo, R.F. (2005). Funding Source, Board Involvement Techniques, and Financial Vulnerability in Nonprofit Organizations: A Test of Resource Dependence. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 16 (2), 171190. Jimenez, B.S. (2013). Strategic Planning and the Fiscal Performance of City Governments during the Great Recession. American Review of Public Administration, 43 (5), 581-601. Keating, E., Fischer, M., Gordon, T., and Greenlee, J. (2005). Assessing Financial Vulnerability in the Nonprofit Sector. Faculty Research Working Paper Series, No.27, Hauser Center for Nonprofit Organizations. Page | 16 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 Lampkin, L.M., and Boris, E.T. (2002). Nonprofit Organization Data: What We Have and What We Need. American Behavioral Scientist, 45 (11), 1675-1715. LeRoux, K., and Wright, N.S. (2013). Does Performance Measurement Improve Strategic Decision Making: Findings from a National Survey of Nonprofit Social Services. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 39 (4), 571-587. Martin, L.L. & Kettner, P.M. (2010). Measuring the Performance of Human Service Programs. Los Angeles, CA: Sage. Mayer, W.J., Wang, H., Egginton, J.F., and Flint, H.S. (2014). The Impact of Revenue Diversification on Expected Revenue and Volatility for Nonprofit Organizations. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 43 (2), 374-392. Moore, M.H. (2000). Managing for Value: Organizational Strategy in For-Profit, Nonprofit, and Governmental Organizations. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 29 (1), 183-204. Mosley, J.E., Maronick, M.P., and Katz, H. (2012). How Organizational Characteristics Affect the Adaptive Tactics used by Human Service Nonprofit Managers Confronting Financial Uncertainty. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 22 (3), 281-303. Poister, T.H., and Streib, G. (2005). Elements of Strategic Planning and Management in Municipal Government: Status after Two Decades. Public Administration Review, 65 (1), 45-56. Poister, T.H., Pitts, D.W., and Edwards, L.H. (2010). Strategic Management Research in the Public Sector: A Review, Synthesis, and Future Directions. The American Review of Public Administration, 40 (5), 522-545. Preston, J.B., and Brown, W.A. (2004). Commitment and Performance of Nonprofit Board Members. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 15 (2), 221-238. Ritchie, W.J., and Kolodinsky, R.W. (2003). Nonprofit Organization Financial Performance Measurement: An Evaluation of New and Existing Financial Performance Measures. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 13 (4), 367381. Siciliano, J.I. (2006). The Relationship between Formal Planning and Performance in Nonprofit Organizations. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 7 (4), 387-403. Page | 17 Q. Hu & N. Kapucu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 1-18 Stone, M.M., Bigelow, B., and Crittenden, W. (1999). Research on Strategic Management in Nonprofit Organizations: Synthesis, Analysis, and Future Directions. Administration and Society, 31 (1), 378-423. Teller. E. (2012). Lessons Learned on Conducting the Strategic Planning Process for a Nonprofit: What Went Right and What Could be Improved. Journal for Nonprofit Management, 15 (1), 50-64. Trussel, J., Greenlee, J.S., and Brady, T. (2002). Predicting Financial Vulnerability in Charitable Organizations. The CPA Journal, 72 (6), 66-69. Trussel, J.M. (2002). Revisiting the Prediction of Financial Vulnerability. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 13 (1), 17-31. Tuckman, H.P., and Chang, C.F. (1991). A Methodology for Measuring the Financial Vulnerability of Charitable Nonprofit Organizations. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 20 (4), 445-460. Yan, W., Denison, D.V., and Butler, J.S. (2009). Revenue Structure and Nonprofit Borrowing. Public Finance Review, 37 (1), 47-67. Zimmermann, J.A.M., and Stevens, B.W. (2008). Best Practices in Board Governance: Evidence from South Carolina. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 19 (2), 189-202. Page | 18 European Journal of Economic and Political Studies 8 (2015) 19-42 A Critical Review of Theoretical Perspectives on Emerging Economy Multinationals Yüksel AYDEN * Department of Management, Fatih University, Turkey Abstract This study provides a critical review of the mainstream (i.e. internationalization process model and eclectic paradigm) and emergent perspectives (i.e. springboard perspective and linkage, leverage, and learning model) on internationalization process of emerging economy multinational enterprises (EE MNEs). It discusses the theoretical knowledge on multinational enterprise (MNE) behavior by providing the contributions of each perspective to the literature, their explanations about EE MNEs’ international expansion, as well as the extensions, modifications, and criticism made on them. The comparative discussion of the extant literature demonstrates that each theoretical perspective explains a particular trajectory of MNE internationalization; therefore, an integration of the current perspectives on MNE internationalization is needed. Key Words: Emerging Economy Multinationals, Internationalization, Outward Foreign Direct Investment JEL Classification: F23, M16, L10. * Tel: +90 (212) 866 3300/5052 E-mail address: [email protected] Note: This paper is generated from the author's Ph.D. dissertation submitted to Graduate School of Social Sciences at Fatih University. Page | 19 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 1. Introduction Internationalization of a firm has been explained in international business (IB) literature from different perspectives for several decades. A number of theories and models were developed by IB scholars that aim to explain multinational enterprise (MNE) internationalization. Almost all of these theoretical contributions were made by studying on developed economy multinational enterprise (DE MNE) as a research phenomenon (Buckley et al., 2007; Ramamurti, 2012). A focus on DE MNEs was reasonable at the previous decades since the global foreign direct investment (FDI) movements were mostly conducted by the MNEs originated from triad economies (i.e. USA, EU and Japan). However, as the percentage of emerging economies’ outward FDI (OFDI) within the overall global investments enhanced (UNCTAD, 2014), multinationals originated from these economies have attracted the attention of scholars and various research questions have arisen such as “whether these firms represent a new type of MNE or not?” or “whether existing IB theories are adequate to explain their behaviors or not?” (Mathews, 2006; Narula, 2006; Ramamurti, 2012; Jormanainen and Koveshnikov, 2012). In IB literature, there exists a debate around these questions and a considerable amount of research has been conducted by the scholars regarding the emerging economy multinational enterprise (EE MNE) behaviors such as determinants of their OFDI (Yamakawa, Peng, and Deeds, 2008; Buckley et al., 2007), their internationalization strategies (Tsai and Eisingerich 2010), location choices (Filatotchev et al., 2007; Makino, Lau, and Yeh 2002), and entry modes (Demirbag, Tatoglu, and Glaister, 2009). In general, there are three different approaches in IB field to the current debate about the EE MNEs’ global expansion (Ramamurti, 2012; Jormanainen and Koveshnikov, 2012). First, some scholars argue that EE MNEs are a new type of MNE in terms of their organizational forms and strategies (Mathews, 2006). According to this view, existing theories are not adequate to explain EE MNE internationalization since they were developed by studying DE MNEs. These scholars suggest developing new theories by specifically focusing on EE MNEs and the environment from which they have been emerging (Ramamurti, 2012; Mathews, 2006; Luo and Tung, 2007; Luo and Rui, 2009). Contrary to the first view, some scholars address that existing IB theories are quite adequate to explain international expansion of EE MNEs (Dunning, 2006; Ramamurti, 2012; Narula, 2006). Another third group of scholars proposes to extend and refine the previously developed theories (Meyer and Thaijongrak, 2012; Jormanainen and Koveshnikov, 2012). These scholars agree that existing IB theories were developed based on the research on DE MNEs, and IB field is heavily influenced by western experience. However, they assert that research on internationalization of these DE MNEs began by the 1970s Page | 20 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 when many of the DE MNEs had already internationalized to some degree. In other words, earlier international investments of DE MNEs had been made for several decades when the scholars began to examine their internationalization processes and FDIs. Thus, there is a lack of explanation about the earlier stages of MNE internationalization. In this context, EE MNEs may provide a fruitful research laboratory for the scholars to complete this gap by drawing a complete picture of the internationalization of the firm (Ramamurti, 2012). This paper attempts to review the mainstream and emergent theoretical perspectives on EE MNE internationalization in order to discover theoretical inconsistencies about firm internationalization and to shed some light on future research for MNE behavior. In IB field, Dunning’s eclectic paradigm (Narula, 2010; Cantwell and Narula, 2001; Narula, 2006; Erdener and Shapiro, 2005; Dunning, 1980, 1988, 2000, 2001) and internationalization process model (or Uppsala model) (Johanson and Vahlne, 1977; Meyer and Thaijongrak, 2012; Johanson and Vahlne, 2009; Forsgren, 2002; Clark, Pugh, and Mallory, 1997) are two fundamental frameworks that are used to explain MNE internationalization. There are also more recent contributions particularly focusing on EE MNEs, which are mostly cited and discussed in IB field. This work includes two of these emergent perspectives that are springboard perspective (Luo and Tung, 2007) and linkage, leverage, and learning (LLL) model (Mathews, 2006) as additional research lenses to examine EE MNE internationalization. The rationale behind this selection is that among others springboard perspective and LLL model address the novelty of EE MNEs and their arguments are mostly commented and cited in the recent studies on EE MNEs (Dunning, 2006; Erdilek, 2008; Jormanainen & Koveshnikov, 2012; Lu et al., 2011; Luo & Rui, 2009; Meyer & Thaijongrak, 2012; Narula, 2006; Yamakawa et al., 2008; Yaprak & Karademir, 2010). 2. Mainstream Perspectives on EE MNEs Internationalization has been studied from various dimensions in IB literature. Since IB field is an eclectic area in nature, theoretical knowledge generated in the field is largely depended on the inspirations and borrowings from related fields such as economics, strategy, and organization theory. As a result of this eclecticism, roots of perspectives explaining the research phenomena of the field vary to a great extent. The internationalization process model (IPM) that explains the internationalization process of the firm is mostly based on behavioral theories (Melin, 1992), whereas Dunning’s eclectic paradigm or OLI Framework integrates transaction cost economics and internalization theory to explain FDI. Page | 21 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 2.1. Internationalization Process Model The IPM proposes that firm increases its resource commitment abroad as it acquires knowledge about the foreign markets and incrementally expands its foreign operations based on a incremental learning process (Johanson and Vahlne, 1977, 1990; Johanson and Wiedersheim-Paul, 1975). It describes internationalization as a stage process in which a series of incremental decisions made about the international activities of the firm based on the knowledge acquisition through firm’s own experience (Johanson and Wiedersheim-Paul, 1975). The IPM explains firm internationalization as a different pattern of growth. The firm international expansion is not seen as a set of deliberately planned steps built on rational analysis by the IPM. Instead, the main characteristic of the internationalization process is the incremental nature of successive learning through stages of increasing commitment to international markets (Melin, 1992). The model proposes that firms firstly begin internationalization in countries that are culturally and geographically close to their country of origin (Johanson and Vahlne, 1977; Casillas, Acedo, and Barbero, 2010). At the beginning of internationalization the amount of the resources committed to the foreign market is small since firms prefer less risky international operation types such as exporting instead of making FDI. As external market knowledge is acquired, firm increases the amount of resource commitment and expands its international scope as well. Therefore, the IPM approaches internationalization as a pathdependent learning process in which the amount of resources committed to foreign markets are dependent on the amount of knowledge acquired based on experiential learning (Andersen, 1993; Eriksson, Majkgård, and Sharma, 2000). The knowledge gained during this process is based on the experiences with customers, markets, and competitors (i.e. market-based knowledge), the experiences within the institutional framework (i.e. institutional knowledge), and the experiences derived from working in foreign markets (i.e. internationalization knowledge) (Casillas, Acedo, and Barbero, 2010; Clark, Pugh, and Mallory, 1997). The IPM presents an incremental internationalization in small steps due to the rationale that managers are risk-averse, and they expand their businesses as they seize new opportunities in their local business environment. It depends on the observations that companies internationalize in their nearby countries in terms of culture, institutions, educational level, and language by first using sales agents and then making FDI (Barkema and Drogendijk, 2007; Johanson and Wiedersheim-Paul, 1975). In other words, dissimilarities between foreign markets and home country create a psychic distance that discourages firms to begin their international operations in countries where political, economic, cultural, and Page | 22 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 linguistic differences are high (Johanson and Vahlne, 1990; Johanson and Wiedersheim-Paul, 1975; Barkema and Drogendijk, 2007). Psychic distance is a result of the various discrepancies that firm experiences between its home and host countries in terms of language, education, business practices, culture, and task environment. It is a key factor in determining the pattern of firm internationalization across borders (Richardson, 2014). Other scholars suggest that institutional distance that is the variations in the regulatory, cognitive, and normative environments is also a significant determinant of firm internationalization pattern (Kostova and Zaheer, 1999; Kostova, Roth, and Dacin, 2008; Kostova, 1999; Xu and Shenkar, 2002). Ghemawat (2001) describes four different types of distance that are cultural distance (e.g. differences in religious beliefs, race, social norms, and language between home and host countries); administrative or political distance (e.g. colony-colonizer links, common currency, and trade arrangements); geographic distance (the physical distance between the two countries, the size of the target country, transportation and communications infrastructures); and economic distance (e.g. differences in the two countries' consumer income and variations in the cost and quality of resources). It is also argued that firm internationalization is a regional effort, not a global one as a result of distance (Jansson and Sandberg, 2008; Ghemawat, 2001; Richardson, 2014). Research on the relation between incremental expansion and MNE performance demonstrate conflicting results. Some scholars assert that incremental learning from experiences reduces the failure rate of company investments (Barkema, Bell, & Pennings, 1996; Li, 1995) while in recent studies others argue that incremental expansion may not be the best option for the firm overall performance (e.g. profitability) (Delios and Beamish, 2001; Barkema and Drogendijk, 2007). Moreover regarding the EE MNEs, some scholars state that EE MNEs internationalize differently in terms of speed and scope than the IPM proposes (Mathews, 2006; Guillén and García-Canal, 2009; Madhok and Keyhani, 2012). In many cases, EE MNEs enter the markets that are not physically close to their home countries; rather they enter the dissimilar and distant countries from their home (Ramamurti, 2004). They use more risky, but faster options to internationalize such as mergers and acquisitions instead of beginning with low risks such as using sales agents or sales subsidiaries (Madhok and Keyhani, 2012; Ramamurti, 2012). This more accelerated internationalization of EE MNEs might be associated with a set of factors changing the global business environment. As a result of the high costs of innovation, short product life cycles, and the multiple technological competences needed for today’s products –particularly in certain industries- firms Page | 23 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 should internationalize rapidly rather than incrementally (Narula, 2006). Under these circumstances, EE MNEs became more willing to act as global players to compensate their late-comer disadvantages by acquiring assets and competences that they lack (Child and Rodrigues, 2005). The path-dependent internationalization can generate returns for the firm in the short-run, but such a risk-averse expansion may not be applicable in the long-run (Barkema and Drogendijk, 2007). Therefore, in a case of rapid internationalization the IPM becomes insufficient to explain the internationalization of the firm, especially in the case of EE MNEs. Moreover, firms, regardless of their country of origin, in certain industries (e.g. information and communication technologies) cannot be risk averse and cannot make incremental moves due to the fierce competition and high market dynamism (Narula, 2006). Furthermore, the existence of born global firms (Knight and Cavusgil, 2004) that skip the incremental stages and early internationalize from or near their founding shadows over the accuracy of traditional internationalization process model of the firm. Thus, the argument proposed by the IPM that is firms incrementally expand to the close markets in terms of cultural, geographical or institutional proximity may not be generalizable (Richardson, 2014). As a concluding remark Cantwell and Narula (2001) state that the internationalization sequence argument that is firms first export and then make direct investments is mostly abandoned. 2.2. Eclectic Paradigm The eclectic paradigm is a comprehensive framework developed by John Dunning in a series of publications (Dunning, 1980, 1983, 1988, 2000, 2001) to explain firm foreign direct investment. It offers an overall framework for firms’ FDIs by integrating views from transaction cost economics, internalization theory, and resource-based view (RBV) of the firm. It was Coase (1937) who was the first recognizing that the operation of the market costs something that are transaction, contracting, and coordinating costs of using the price mechanism. To avoid these transaction costs, firms can use their vertically integrated structures to set transfer prices by controlling the production and marketing of an intermediate product inside the organization. These fundamental insights from transaction cost economics are more applicable to the MNEs. Since there are more imperfections and greater transaction costs for the firms in international markets than in domestic markets, it could be assumed that internalization might result in efficiency, thus, firms engaging in FDI take place in global business landscape (Rugman, 1980). Page | 24 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 Transaction cost economics view gave birth to internalization theory that sees firm’s expansion through FDI as a mean to decrease transaction costs resulting from coordination of activities across national boundaries (Buckley and Casson, 1976; Rugman, 1980; Filatotchev et al., 2007). In other words, internalization can happen in response to externalities in the goods or factor markets. Distortions in the goods market, such as a tariff, will encourage FDI and multinationality. The explicit recognition of these worldwide market imperfections, which in practice causes inefficiencies in international operations, lay at the heart of the internalization theory. Internalization theory argues that the MNEs take place in the global landscape due to the market failures such as exogenous government induced regulations and controls that spoil the theoretical reasons for free trade and private foreign investment. The internalization process, here, allows the firm to overcome such externalities and governmental regulations in the product market (Rugman, 1980). The internalization theory developed by Buckley and Casson (1976) and Rugman (1980) is a firm-level theory that aims to explain the reasons that MNEs attempt to control their firm-specific advantages (FSAs). In internalization theory, FSAs such as knowledge advantage arising from a transaction cost economics explanation; and other types of FSAs like brand advantage and organizational capabilities are all efficiency-based and in line with the RBV of the firm. Therefore, it could be argued that internalization theory employs transaction cost economics and RBV to explain the firms’ FDI (Rugman, 2010). In contrast to internalization theory, eclectic paradigm applies new variables to explain FDI. According to eclectic paradigm, the international activities of multinationals are determined by three different but related factors. These factors are ownership (O) advantages, location (L) advantages and internalization (I) advantages. Eclectic paradigm —also known as OLI paradigm argues that these three distinct sets of advantages explain the rationale behind the firm’s involvement in FDI activities. It uses transaction costs and factor costs as its main explanatory variables and assumes that FDI decisions are made rationally within international firms (Melin, 1992). Eclectic paradigm asserts that MNEs have competitive advantages or Oadvantages against their rivals. They exploit these advantages by establishing subsidiaries in attractive foreign countries due to the available L-advantages (Dunning 1980, 1988, 2000, 2001; Cantwell and Narula, 2001). According to Dunning, O-advantages can be distinguished in two types; the first is the ownership advantages of unique tangible and intangible assets (such as firmspecific technology); and the second one is the ownership of complementary Page | 25 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 assets (such as the ability to coordinate cross-border activities effectively) (Cantwell and Narula, 2001). He clearly distinguished these two types of ownership advantages as asset-based ownership (Oa) advantages and transaction-type ownership (Ot) advantages later (Dunning, 1983; Eden and Dai, 2010). Oa-advantages arise from the ownership of specific assets such as intellectual property rights in the forms of trademarks and patents or tacit knowledge and tangible property and equipment. They are in line with the RBV (Barney, 1991) which argues that the firm should possess valuable resources that are difficult to imitate and rare to sustain its competitive position. Ot-advantages are the economies achieved from the common governance of a network of assets located in different countries (Lundan, 2010). They are firm-specific assets and related to effective management of transactions that allows the firm to generate economic rent. The use of markets and intra-firm hierarchies across national borders may create an advantage to the firm even Oa-advantages are same or even inferior to its rivals (Narula, 2006). Later, Dunning and Lundan (2008a) defined a new type of ownership advantage that is institutional (Oi) advantages which refers to the ability of the multinationals to manage their relationships outside the firm boundaries both in home and host-country institutional environments. Table 1 summarizes the three types of O-advantages. Table 1. The Nature and Content of Different Ownership Advantages Advantage Contents Property rights and/or intangible asset advantages Product innovations, production management, organizational and marketing systems, innovatory capacity, noncodifable knowledge; accumulated Oa experience in marketing, finance etc. Ability to reduce intra and/ or inter-firm transactions (also influenced by Oi) Advantages of common governance Advantages of scale and scope of the multiplant Ot firm. Advantages specifically derived from multinationality itself (also influenced by Oi) Institutional advantages The formal and informal institutions that govern the value-added processes within the firm, and between Oi the firm and its stakeholders. Codes of conduct, norms, and corporate culture; incentive systems and appraisal; leadership and management of diversity Source: Lundan (2010, p. 55) Page | 26 Outcomes Efficiency Market power Organizational effectiveness Legitimacy and trust resulting nonmarket effectiveness Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 The second variable in eclectic paradigm is L-advantages. Eclectic paradigm argues that firms engaging in IB activities choose FDI rather than other types of IB operations to take advantages of location bounded advantages in any foreign countries. Examples of L-advantages may include the spatial distribution of natural resource endowments, input prices, quality and productivity benefits, and transportation and communication costs. The government policies such as investment incentives, strong legal and regulatory systems such as well protection of propriety rights can be considered other types of L-advantages for the rationale of FDI (Dunning and Lundan, 2008b). This sub-paradigm argues that the more the immobile, natural or created resource endowments that firms needs to use besides their O-advantages are available in a foreign country rather than a domestic location, firms will choose to exploit or enhance their O-advantages by engaging in FDI (Dunning, 2000). In other words, L-advantages can be the reason for decisions to invest in a foreign country where superior procurement, production, and market opportunities are available that allow the firm to use its existing resources and capabilities (Child and Rodrigues, 2005). L-advantages rest on the assumption that firms seek to locate their value adding activities at the most suitable points with the most favorable conditions in space. Therefore, the location choices of MNEs depend on their motives for FDIs (Dunning, 2001). The third variable in eclectic paradigm is the internalization advantages resulting from the internal usage of O-advantages rather than using them in the open market. Many alternative ways exist to create or exploit firm core competencies. For instance, firms may prefer to buy and sell their products in the open market or through inter-firm non-equity agreements. Alternatively, firms may prefer to integrate the intermediate product markets to avoid from transaction costs. Likewise internalization theory, eclectic paradigm argues that firms prefer to internalize cross-border intermediate markets through FDIs when the net benefits are greater than other types of IB activities like licensing (Dunning, 2000). The eclectic paradigm aims to integrate the elements of transaction cost, internalization theory, and RBV of the firm to explain the international production of MNEs. However, it is not possible to synthesize a set of theories that address different questions by relying on different views, and the eclectic paradigm is not intended to do so. Thus, it is not itself another theory, instead it provides an overall analytical framework that draws the investigators attention to the most important theories for the problem that they seek to address (Cantwell and Narula, 2001, 2006). Page | 27 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 Scholars have been discussing the eclectic paradigm in order to explain EE MNE behavior. The main principle of the eclectic paradigm is that to become an MNE a firm must hold considerable ownership advantages (Dunning, 2001; Ramamurti, 2012). According to Mathews (2006), EE MNEs do not possess traditional ownership advantages. Instead, they have organizational skills as their primary advantage. However, Narula (2006) posits that these organizational skills are not incompatible with the propositions of the eclectic paradigm instead they suit with the definition of Ot-advantages in OLI framework. Madhok and Keyhani (2012) approach the O-advantages of EE MNEs from a different perspective. They argue that EE MNEs possess only ordinary resources that are not traditionally mentioned among the resources that generate extraordinary returns such as high technology and brand. In a similar vein, Rugman (2009) asserts that EE MNE internationalization is a result of exploitation of their home country comparative advantages such as cheap labor and natural resources. However, Ramamurti (2012) sees these explanations unsatisfactory and posits that home country location advantages cannot provide long-run competitive advantage since they are available to all firms in a given location too. He states that EE MNEs possess ownership advantages, but they are not the same advantages that scholars are used to seeing in DE MNEs. Thus, EE MNEs need to be investigated to explore their unconventional O-advantages such as their ability to function in difficult environments, their understanding of customer needs in emerging markets and their abilities to develop low-cost products for emerging market customers (Ramamurti, 2012; Cuervo-Cazurra and Genc, 2008; Guillén and García-Canal, 2009; Ramamurti and Singh, 2009). Perhaps the most significant difference between DE MNE and EE MNE internationalization in terms of O-advantages that many scholars argue that EE MNEs lack valuable O-advantages, thus their OFDIs can be understood better by asset-seeking motivations (Mathews, 2006; Madhok and Keyhani, 2012; Luo and Tung, 2007). Considerable amount of evidence exist to support that EE MNEs are seeking valuable assets such as technologies and brands (Gubbi et al., 2009; Lu et al., 2011; Makino et al., 2002; Tsai & Eisingerich, 2010; Yaprak & Karademir, 2010). However, this explanation can be inadequate to assert that they internationalize without O-advantages (Ramamurti, 2012). There are some arguments that EE MNEs have developed their own O-advantages such as flexibility, familiarity with emerging market contexts, and the ability to develop beneficial relations with firms and other actors to access the resources that they lack (Buckley et al., 2007; Erdener and Shapiro, 2005; Luo and Rui, 2009). The discrepancy between EE MNE and DE MNE O-advantages might be a reflection of the differences of their evolutionary stages. EE MNEs are at the beginning of their Page | 28 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 internationalization (Ramamurti and Singh, 2009) and with time they augment their O-advantages and become more like DE MNEs. Since DE MNEs had more time to develop their capabilities, they possess distinctive capabilities (Ramamurti, 2012). Some critiques of the broad definitions of OLI variables exist. Rugman (2010) states that one of the problems of Dunning’s eclectic paradigm is that it has overdetermined the three motives for FDI, especially O-advantages. In eclectic paradigm, the definition of O-advantages is broad and includes not only the firm intangible assets such as knowledge, brand, organizational structure, and managerial skills but also Ricardian factor endowments such as capital, manpower, and natural resources. Besides, legal and institutional environment and industry market structure are included in O-advantages. However, the latter set of O-advantages is country-specific advantages and it is easier to analyze these advantages from country level instead of accepting them as O-advantages. Again Dunning argued that these location-based advantages can be turned into Oadvantages but as discussed earlier these are available to all firms embedded in the same location (Rugman, 2010). In addition, Rugman criticizes the very broad definition of L-advantages including market size, natural resources, education system and other types of political and government activity. This broad definition makes it difficult to distinct O-advantages and L-advantages. For instance, when an MNE is allowed to access to natural resources such as a mine, L-advantages of that host country is transformed into an O-advantage (Rugman, 2010). In addition to the ongoing debate on eclectic paradigm above, the rise of EE MNEs in the global markets brings new questions to the discussion and offers new opportunities. A potential contribution of the studies on EE MNEs might be a clearer portray of O-, L-, and I-advantages as well as a more sharpened categorization of these variables. For instance, Ramamurti (2012) states that what is needed is an exploration of EE MNEs’ O-advantages without being limited to the traditionally mentioned ones and to be more open-minded for novel forms of Oadvantages. 3. Emergent Perspectives on EE MNEs As discussed earlier, perhaps the most significant discussion in IB field is whether EE MNEs represent a new type of firm that requires novel theories or their internationalization can be explained with the mainstream theories of the field with some extensions (Ramamurti, 2012; Jormanainen and Koveshnikov, 2012). Many scholars agree that there is a need for theoretical extensions for the existing theories (Buckley et al., 2007; Cuervo-Cazurra and Genc, 2008; Cuervo- Page | 29 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 Cazurra, 2008) whereas others insist that existing theories be still suitable to explain EE MNEs internationalization (Dunning, 2006). However, new perspectives and models have been developed demonstrating the distinctiveness of EE MNEs internationalization such as springboard perspective (Luo and Tung, 2007) and LLL model (Mathews, 2006). 3.1. Springboard Perspective The springboard perspective developed by Luo and Tung (2007) to point out that EE MNEs use internationalization as a springboard to overcome their latecomer disadvantages by acquiring the strategic assets that they lack and to counter-attack their rivals in their home markets. EE MNEs also use OFDI in order to reduce the institutional and market constraints in their home markets as well as to bypass rigid trade barriers and international constraints by either assetseeking or opportunity-seeking FDIs. The argument that is EE MNEs internationalize not only to exploit their ownership advantages but also to acquire valuable strategic assets is also supported by other studies (Klein and Wöcke, 2007; Chittoor and Ray, 2007). In particular, the springboard perspective argues that unlike DE MNEs, EE MNEs are not often path dependent nor evolutionary in terms of location choices and entry modes. Instead, by a series of aggressive, proactive and risk taking measures they expand their operations in both developed and emerging markets via high-control, high-risk entry modes such as acquisitions and greenfield investments. These strategies can be reasonable when the low-cost advantages of these firms are considered. EE MNEs’ acquisitions largely target brands and technology that may add differentiation advantages to their existing cost advantages. In addition, these quick and radical internationalization also accelerates their further market entries and internationalization process by increasing their reputations (Luo and Tung, 2007). Luo and Tung (2007) identify a number of activities undertaken by EE MNEs that expresses the “springboarding”. First, EE MNEs internationalize to compensate their competitive disadvantages by seeking sophisticated technology or advanced manufacturing know-how in developed markets. Second, EE MNEs lessen their latecomer disadvantages in areas such as brand recognition and consumer base by engaging in FDIs. To offset these competitive disadvantages and latecomer deficiencies, EE MNEs use internationalization as a springboard and engage in strategic asset-seeking FDIs in developed markets. Third, EE MNEs engage in market-seeking FDIs to counterattack their global rivals that have been penetrating their home country markets. Particularly large EE MNEs attempt to gain customers in advanced markets like USA, Japan, and Europe. Fourth, EE MNEs use FDI as a mean to bypass the trade barriers in host countries (e.g., quota Page | 30 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 restrictions, anti-dumping penalties, and special tariff penalties). Particularly EE MNEs manufacturing technologically standardized products are heavily dependent on export markets. Here, FDI is used as a springboard to reach the overseas customers and end users. Fifth, EE MNEs internationalize to alleviate their home country institutional constraints such as weak legal systems, political instability, government interference, and inefficient market intermediaries. These institutional voids and political hazards erode the firm competitiveness, thus, push them to internationalize. Sixth, EE MNEs makes reverse investments to get the preferential treatment offered by emerging economy governments. They invest in a foreign country and create a subunit at first. Then, they invest back to their home by using this subunit to get the financial or non-financial privileges given by their home country governments. Lastly, in springboard perspective, it is expressed that EE MNEs uses internationalization as a springboard to exploit their ownership advantages in emerging countries (Luo and Tung, 2007). At this point, unlike the arguments asserted by Ramamurti (2012), springboard perspective does not claim that EE MNEs internationalize without O-advantages instead it argues that EE MNEs also internationalize to exploit their existing competitive advantages in emerging markets. The springboard perspective offers valuable insights for EE MNEs. It provides a general picture of their behaviors and the characteristics of their institutional environments. However, most of the behaviors associated to EE MNEs in springboard view are realized by also DE MNEs. The activities defined as a “springboard” could be observable in any MNE regardless of its origin. 3.2. Linkage, Leverage, and Learning Model Another perspective specifically focuses on the uniqueness of EE MNEs internationalization is the linkage, leverage and learning (LLL) model proposed by Mathews (2006). LLL model argues that EE MNEs are resource-poor. Thus, they engage in asset-seeking activities to internalize and transform acquired assets into dynamic capabilities that are keys to competitiveness. In LLL model, in order to internalize and transform the dynamic capabilities, a firm needs to linkages to generate opportunities for resource acquisitions, leverages to exploit established resource linkages, and learning as a repeated applications of linkages and leverages (Yaprak and Karademir, 2010). LLL model states that EE MNEs’ advantages arisen from external environments not form their internal sides. In other words, they have the opportunity to pay off their latecomer disadvantages by acquiring them externally. Thus, according to LLL model, international expansion is a source of Page | 31 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 advantage and a necessity for the EE MNEs. At this point, the risk and uncertainties can be reduced by joint-ventures and other forms of partnerships. After establishing a linkage, leveraging the resources is the following concern for the EE MNE to receive the strategic end that is learning in the proposed model (Li, 2007; Mathews, 2006). LLL model argues that firms that are originated from emerging economies are a novel type of MNEs and make some of the concepts of the existing IB literature less useful. Mathews (2006) discusses the characteristics of the new global business system and the success of the newcomer and latecomer firms from peripheral areas such as the Asia Pacific by associating these Dragon multinationals’ success to their strategic innovations, organizational innovations, and accelerated internationalization. He points out that Dragon multinationals adopt a different perspective on the resources that they acquire through internationalization and suggests a rethink of the RBV of strategy and dominant eclectic paradigm of IB field. LLL model is mostly criticized especially due to its challenges on O-advantages of the eclectic paradigm. Ramamurti (2012) assert that LLL model uses the same initials as the OLI framework. Narula (2006) states that asset-seeking activities are not new for MNEs since MNEs have engaged in this type of FDI for quite a while. Thus, what is LLL model describes is not a novel idea, and nor is it unique; it has just been more common in EE MNEs. Moreover, the argument that is EE MNEs do not possess O-advantages might not be valid, particularly in the more R&Dintensive sectors. For instance; Samsung has over 200,000 employees and has invested $4.6 billion in R&D activities by the year 2003. Its establishment date goes back to the 1930s, and it is more like an incumbent rather than a newcomer. Furthermore, Mathews (2006) is criticized about the terminology that he used in developing his LLL model such as dragon MNEs, third world multinationals, latecomer, and newcomer MNEs. LLL model is based on the review of the experiences of latecomer and newcomer MNEs such as Acer, Ispat International, Li & Fung, and the Hong Leong Group. These firms, however, are hard to classify in terms of industry, size, age or organization (Narula, 2006). 4. Theoretical Inconsistencies between Mainstream and Emergent Perspectives The existence of EE MNEs discloses that there exist two seemingly inconsistent themes about the existing literature on the internationalization of MNEs. The first theme is the nature of the internationalization process. Although the original IPM proposes an incremental internationalization process, many EE MNEs expand their operations in a radical way by skipping the stages that the IPM Page | 32 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 predicted. The second theme is about the firm motives for foreign expansion. Both mainstream perspectives, whether implicitly or explicitly, argue that internationalization occurs as a result of firm motive to exploit its ownership advantages. However, explorative motives have been more observable as EE MNEs has taken a significant position in global marketplaces. Therefore, the second theme that requires further discussion is the exploitative and explorative motives for FDI. 4.1. Theoretical Inconsistency #1: Incremental vs. Radical Internationalization The central argument of the IPM is that firms follow an incremental process through experiential learning during their internationalization. They commit more resources as they increase their local market knowledge incrementally. The model uses psychic distance concept to predict the location choices and entry strategies of MNEs (Johanson and Vahlne, 1977). When the findings in the extant literature are considered (Meyer and Thaijongrak, 2012; Chetty and Campbell-Hunt, 2004) it is seen that arguments of IPM about the internationalization of the firm still keep their explanatory power to some extent. Firms usually engage in other forms of international activities in a particular market prior to their direct investments. This development path is also discovered in the literature about the EE MNEs (CuervoCazurra, 2008). Many firms from emerging economies take a longtime to be MNEs, and they choose the countries that are geographically and culturally close to their home countries (Erdilek, 2008). However, there are some exceptions in the literature. Some firms demonstrate deviations from the linear predictions of the IPM. Particularly, EE MNEs suffer from the disadvantages of being latecomers follow a more radical route that the IPM proposes. They pursue a rapid way to internationalize to compensate their latecomers disadvantages by skipping the stages predicted by IPM. In addition to this, EE MNEs use their networks and managerial ties with other parties to accelerate their internationalization (Mathews, 2006). This view is in line with the network view that has been added to the refined version of the original IPM (Johanson and Vahlne, 2009). As discussed earlier the stage model is also criticized by the researcher due to the rise of the born global firms. Ramamurti (2012) states that, the world is now flatter than previous decades when DE MNEs experiences were examined, and mainstream IB perspectives were developed. As Johanson and Vahlne (2009) pointed out that the emerging phenomena such as leapfrogging and born-global firms are not included in the original IPM because they were not common among the Swedish firms these scholars analyzed at that time. Specifically, acquisitions made by EE MNEs facilitate the internalization of the tangible and intangible resources that take time to develop internally and speed Page | 33 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 up their internationalization (Gubbi et al., 2009). Their network ties with the hostcountry government and organizations operating in the industries to be positioned may accelerate the process by rapid transformation of the market knowledge. Therefore, networks and partnerships may result in a more quick way of gathering institutional market knowledge (Eriksson et al., 1997) and might decrease the liability of outsidership in a short time (Johanson and Vahlne, 2009). This accelerated internationalization is addressed in springboard perspective and LLL model as a distinctive feature for EE MNEs. These emergent perspectives stress the latecomer disadvantages of EE MNEs, and the learning imperative to catch up early movers (Mathews, 2006; Luo and Tung, 2007). To conclude, although internationalization through rapid and risky steps appear in the cases of DE MNEs, EE MNEs has made it more explicit that MNEs can internationalize in a radical way by passing out the stages in so-called establishment chain. 4.2. Theoretical Inconsistency #2: Exploitative vs.Explorative Internationalization The IPM and the eclectic paradigm argue that firms expand to foreign countries to exploit their firm-specific advantages. Although their firm competences are different from the DE MNEs’ competences, EE MNEs hold Oadvantages to be exploited in the foreign markets offering location advantages. They possess valuable advantages that enable them to engage in FDIs. Besides some conventional O-advantages such as know-how and technology, they hold Oadvantages considered as “ordinary” (Madhok and Keyhani, 2012) such as entrepreneurial skills, cost advantages, and networking abilities. In fact, the concept of advantage is a relative term. It is not logical to evaluate the value of EE MNEs O-advantages by comparing them to DC MNEs’ ones. The value of any firm resource or capability as an advantage depends on the ability of the firm in combining and utilizing them. Even so-called ordinary firm resources and capabilities can be superior when they are exploited in the appropriate locations. Thus, the location choice for EE MNEs or market selection is again important for their internationalization performance. Even though the IPM and the eclectic paradigm have an explanatory power on the EE MNEs exploitative internationalization, there are also some variances in EE MNEs’ experiences when these firms asset-seeking FDIs are considered. EE MNEs exploit not only their firm-specific advantages in foreign markets but also explore new ones. Research on EE MNEs demonstrates that EE MNEs seek international opportunities to upgrade their existing resource bases in an explorative manner. Many EE MNEs use their partnerships with DE MNEs to learn and upgrade their existing firm resources and capabilities (e.g. OEM/ODM experiences as the LLL model argues) (Mathews, 2006). They also engage in Page | 34 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 acquisitions to develop a strong position in global markets rapidly. EE MNEs aggressive FDIs, particularly in developed economies, can be attributed to their latecomer disadvantages. As springboard perspective argues that EE MNEs undertake FDI as a mean, or springboard, to upgrade their competitive advantages. These may include strategic assets such as brands, technology, and design capabilities (Child and Rodrigues, 2005; Luo and Tung, 2007). These assetseeking FDIs also include market-seeking motives. In another saying, EE MNEs’ asset-seeking FDIs are in parallel with their quest for new markets, particularly in developed markets. This argument supports the argument in springboard perspective that EE MNEs internationalize to exploit their competitive advantages as well. At this point, the mainstream IB perspectives highlight the exploitative nature of firm internationalization. However, MNEs also need to explore new firm resources and capabilities while they exploit the existing ones. This situation becomes more explicit for EE MNEs than DE MNEs considering their latecomer disadvantages. As they involve in foreign markets, they feel more competitive pressure, especially for differentiation advantages (Child and Rodrigues, 2005). These findings support the arguments that MNEs need to be ambidextrous that is simultaneous pursue of exploitation and exploration activities (Hsu, Lien, and Chen, 2013; Keen and Wu, 2011; Luo and Rui, 2009). To conclude, although assetseeking motives may be observed in DE MNEs, EE MNEs has made it more explicit that MNEs can internationalize to gain access strategic assets by engaging in FDIs. 5. Conclusion and Future Research Agenda Models or theories provide parsimonious representations of the reality. They shed light on a particular phenomenon, but they also cover some other aspects of it. The cross-sectional research dominating the contemporary management contributes much to our understanding of the specific factors and their effects on specific decisions while neglecting the historical context and the dynamic processes of strategic decisions (Meyer and Thaijongrak, 2012). As shown above, each perspective discussed in this study illuminates certain aspects of EE MNEs internationalization through FDI. IPM predominantly explains the process of internationalization in a dynamic view, whereas eclectic paradigm offers a theoretical framework to understand the FDI transactions. Springboard and LLL model mostly, however, highlight the latecomer characteristics of EE MNEs and their accelerated internationalization. Based on the above discussion, two dimensions are identified that source the recent debates on MNE internationalization. They are the nature of the internationalization process and the firm motives for FDI. For each dimension, there are two categories. The Page | 35 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 nature of the internationalization process varies on a continuum of incremental vs. radical internationalization; whereas the firm motive for FDI can be either asset-exploitation or asset-exploration. Based on these themes, future research should be conducted on MNEs to reveal the nature of the radical internationalization of the firm. Particularly, a focus on born-global EE MNEs that have rapidly internationalized their operations can provide valuable insights to fill the gap in the literature. In addition to this, findings from asset-seeking FDIs of EE MNEs should be examined in order to make a synthesis of mainstream and emergent perspectives. For both research avenues, studies including both DE MNEs and EE MNEs should also be conducted to answer the question that “whether DE MNEs and EE MNEs are truly different from each other or they experience a different stage of evolution?.” References Andersen, O. (1993). On the Internationalization Process of Firms: A Critical Analysis. Journal of International Business Studies, 24 (2), 209–231. Barkema, H.G., Bell, J.H.J., and Pennings, J.M.E. (1996). Foreign Entry, Cultural Barriers and Learning. Strategic Management Journal, 17 (December), 151– 166. Barkema, H.G., and Drogendijk, R. (2007). Internationalising in Small, Incremental or Larger Steps? Journal of International Business Studies, 38 (7), 1132–1148. Barney, J. (1991). Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. Journal of Management, 17 (1), 99–120. Buckley, P.J., Clegg, L.J., Cross, A.R., Liu, X., Voss, H., and Zheng, P. (2007). The Determinants of Chinese Outward Foreign Direct Investment. Journal of International Business Studies, 38 (4), 499–518. Buckley, P.J., and Casson, M. (1976). The Future of Multinational Enterprise. London: Macmillan. Cantwell, J., and Narula, R. (2001). The Eclectic Paradigm in the Global Economy. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 8 (2), 155–172. Casillas, J.C., Acedo, F.J., and Barbero, J.L. (2010). Learning, Unlearning and Internationalisation: Evidence from the Pre-Export Phase. International Journal of Information Management, 30 (2), 162–173. Page | 36 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 Chetty, S., and Campbell-Hunt, C. (2004). A Strategic Approach to Internationalization: A Traditional versus a ‘born-Global’ Approach. Journal of International Marketing, 12 (1), 57–81. Child, J., and Rodrigues, S.B. (2005). The Internationalization of Chinese Firms: A Case for Theoretical Extension? Management and Organization Review, 1 (3), 381–410. Chittoor, R., and Ray, S. (2007). Internationalization Paths of Indian Pharmaceutical Firms — A Strategic Group Analysis. Journal of International Management, 13 (3), 338–355. Clark, T., Pugh, D.S., and Mallory, G. (1997). The Process of Internationalization in the Operating Firm. International Business Review, 6 (6), 605–623. Coase, R.H. (1937). The Nature of the Firm. Economica, 4 (16), 386–405. Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2008). The Multinationalization of Developing Country MNEs: The Case of Multilatinas. Journal of International Management, 14 (2), 138– 154. Cuervo-Cazurra, A., and Genc, M. (2008). Transforming Disadvantages into Advantages: Developing-Country MNEs in the Least Developed Countries. Journal of International Business Studies, 39 (6), 957–979. Delios, A., and Beamish, P.W. (2001). Survival and Profitability: The Roles of Experience and Intangible Assets in Foreign Subsidiary Performance. Academy of Management Journal, 44 (5), 1028–1038. Demirbag, M., Tatoglu, E., and Glaister, K.W. (2009). Equity-Based Entry Modes of Emerging Country Multinationals: Lessons from Turkey. Journal of World Business, 44 (4), 445–462. Dunning, J.H. (1980). Toward an Eclectic Theory of International Production: Some Empirical Tests. Journal of International Business Studies, 11 (1), 9–31. Dunning, J.H. (1983). Market Power of the Firm and International Transfer of Technology. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 1 (4), 333–351. Dunning, J.H. (1988). The Eclectic Paradigm of International Production: A Restatement and Some Possible Extensions. Journal of International Business Studies, 19 (1), 1–31. Dunning, J.H. (2000). The Eclectic Paradigm as an Envelope for Economic and Business Theories of MNE Activity. International Business Review, 9 (2), 163– 190. Page | 37 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 Dunning, J.H. (2001). The Eclectic (OLI) Paradigm of International Production: Past, Present and Future. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 8 (2), 173–190. Dunning, J.H. (2006). Comment on Dragon Multinationals: New Players in 21st Century Globalization. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 23 (2), 139–141. Dunning, J.H., and Lundan, S.M. (2008a). Institutions and the OLI Paradigm of the Multinational Enterprise. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 25 (4), 573– 593. Dunning, J.H., and Lundan, S.M. (2008b). Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Edward Elgar Publishing. Eden, L., and Dai, L. (2010). Rethinking the O in Dunning’s OLI/eclectic Paradigm. Multinational Business Review, 18 (2), 13–34. Erdener, C., and Shapiro, D.M. (2005). The Internationalization of Chinese Family Enterprises and Dunning’s Eclectic MNE Paradigm. Management and Organization Review, 1 (3), 411–436. Erdilek, A. (2008). Internationalization of Turkish MNEs. Journal of Management Development, 27 (7), 744–760. Eriksson, K., Johanson, J., Majkgard, A., and Sharma, D.D. (1997). Experiential Knowledge and Cost in the Internationalization Process. Journal of International Business Studies, 28, 337–360. Eriksson, K., Majkgård, A., and Sharma, D.D. (2000). Path Dependence and Knowledge Development in the Internationalization Process. Management International Review, 40 (4), 307–328. Filatotchev, I., Strange, R., Piesse, J., and Lien, Y.C. (2007). FDI by Firms from Newly Industrialised Economies in Emerging Markets: Corporate Governance, Entry Mode and Location. Journal of International Business Studies, 38 (4), 556–572. Forsgren, M. (2002). The Concept of Learning in the Uppsala Internationalization Process Model: A Critical Review. International Business Review, 11 (3), 257– 277. Ghemawat, P. (2001). Distance Still Matters. The Hard Reality of Global Expansion. Harvard Business Review, 79 (8), 137–147. Gubbi, S.R., Aulakh, P.S., Ray, S., Sarkar, M.B., and Chittoor, R. (2009). Do International Acquisitions by Emerging-Economy Firms Create Shareholder Page | 38 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 Value? The Case of Indian Firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 41 (3), 397–418. Guillén, M.F., and García-Canal, E. (2009). The American Model of the Multinational Firm and the ‘New’ Multinationals From Emerging Economies. Academy of Management Perspectives, 23 (2), 23–35. Hsu, C.W., Lien, Y.C., and Chen, H. (2013). International Ambidexterity and Firm Performance in Small Emerging Economies. Journal of World Business, 48 (1), 58–67. Jansson, H., and Sandberg, S. (2008). Internationalization of Small and Medium Sized Enterprises in the Baltic Sea Region. Journal of International Management, 14 (1), 65–77. Johanson, J., and Vahlne, J.E. (1977). The Internationalization Process of the Firm: A Model of Knowledge Development and Increasing Foreign Market Commitments. Journal of International Business Studies, 8 (1), 23–32. Johanson, J., and Vahlne, J.E. (1990). The Mechanism of Internationalisation. International Marketing Review, 7 (4), 23–32. Johanson, J., and Vahlne, J.E. (2009). The Uppsala Internationalization Process Model Revisited: From Liability of Foreignness to Liability of Outsidership. Journal of International Business Studies, 40 (9), 1411–1431. Johanson, J., and Wiedersheim-Paul, F. (1975). The Internationalization of the Firm: Four Swedish Cases. The Journal of Management Studies, 12 (3), 305– 323. Jormanainen, I., and Koveshnikov, A. (2012). International Activities of Emerging Market Firms. Management International Review, 52 (5), 691–725. Keen, C., and Wu, Y. (2011). An Ambidextrous Learning Model for the Internationalization of Firms from Emerging Economies. Journal of International Entrepreneurship, 9 (4), 316–339. Klein, S., and Wöcke, A. (2007). Emerging Global Contenders: The South African Experience. Journal of International Management, 13 (3), 319–337. Knight, G.A., and Cavusgil, S.T. (2004). Innovation, Organizational Capabilities, and the Born-Global Firm. Journal of International Business Studies, 35 (2), 124– 141. Kostova, T. (1999). Transnational Transfer of Strategic Organizational Practices: A Contextual Perspective. Academy of Management Review, 24 (2), 308–324. Page | 39 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 Kostova, T., Roth, K., and Dacin, M.T. (2008). Institutional Theory in the Study of Multinational Corporations: A Critique and New Directions. Academy of Management Review, 33 (4), 994–1006. Kostova, T., and Zaheer, S. (1999). Organizational Legitimacy under Conditions of Complexity: The Case of the Multinational Enterprise. Academy of Management Review, 24 (1), 64–81. Li, J. (1995). Foreign Entry and Survival: Effects of Strategic Choices on Performance in International Markets. Strategic Management Journal, 16 (5), 333–51. Li, P.P. (2007). Toward an Integrated Theory of Multinational Evolution: The Evidence of Chinese Multinational Enterprises as Latecomers. Journal of International Management, 13 (3), 296–318. Lu, J., Liu, X., and Wang, H. (2011). Motives for Outward FDI of Chinese Private Firms: Firm Resources, Industry Dynamics, and Government Policies. Management and Organization Review, 7 (2), 223–248. Lundan, S.M. (2010). What Are Ownership Advantages? Multinational Business Review, 18 (2), 51–70. Luo, Y., and Rui, H. (2009). An Ambidexterity Perspective toward Multinational Enterprises from Emerging Economies. The Academy of Management Perspectives, 23 (4), 49–70. Luo, Y., and Tung, R.L. (2007). International Expansion of Emerging Market Enterprises: A Springboard Perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 38 (4), 481–98. Madhok, A., and Keyhani, M. (2012). Acquisitions as Entrepreneurship: Asymmetries, Opportunities, and the Internationalization of Multinationals from Emerging Economies. Global Strategy Journal, 2 (1), 26–40. Makino, S., Lau, C.M., and Yeh, R.S. (2002). Asset-Exploitation Versus AssetSeeking: Implications for Location Choice of Foreign Direct Investment from Newly Industrialized Economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 33 (3), 403–421. Mathews, J.A. (2006). Dragon Multinationals: New Players in 21st Century Globalization. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 23 (1), 5–27. Melin, L. (1992). Internationalization as a Strategy Process. Strategic Management Journal, 13 (S2), 99–118. Page | 40 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 Meyer, K.E., and Thaijongrak, O. (2012). The Dynamics of Emerging Economy MNEs: How the Internationalization Process Model Can Guide Future Research. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 30 (4), 1125–1153. Narula, R. (2006). Globalization, New Ecologies, New Zoologies, and the Purported Death of the Eclectic Paradigm. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 23 (2), 143–151. Narula, R. (2010). Keeping the Eclectic Paradigm Simple. Multinational Business Review, 18 (2), 35–50. Ramamurti, R. (2004). Developing Countries and MNEs: Extending and Enriching the Research Agenda. Journal of International Business Studies, 35 (4), 277– 283. Ramamurti, R. (2012). What Is Really Different about Emerging Market Multinationals? Global Strategy Journal, 2 (1), 41–47. Ramamurti, R., and Singh, J. (2009). Emerging Multinationals in Emerging Markets. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Richardson, C. (2014). Firm Internationalisation within the Muslim World. Journal of World Business, 49 (3), 386–395. Rugman, A.M. (1980). Internalization as a General Theory of Foreign Direct Investment: A Re-Appraisal of the Literature. Review of World Economics, 116 (2), 365–379. Rugman, A.M. (2009). Theoretical Aspects of MNEs from Emerging Economies. In R. Ramamurti and J.V. Singh (Eds.), Emerging Multinationals in Emerging Markets (pp. 42–63). Rugman, A.M. (2010). Reconciling Internalization Theory and the Eclectic Paradigm. Multinational Business Review, 18 (2), 1–12. Tsai, H.T., and Eisingerich, A.B. (2010). Internationalization Strategies of Emerging Markets Firms. California Management Review, 53 (1), 114–135. UNCTAD. (2014). World Investment Report 2014. Investing in the SDGs: An Action Plan. Retrieved from unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdf Xu, D., and Shenkar, O. (2002). Note: Institutional Distance and The Multinational Enterprise. Academy of Management Review, 27 (4), 608–618. Yamakawa, Y., Peng, M.W., and Deeds, D.L. (2008). What Drives New Ventures to Internationalize from Emerging to Developed Economies? Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 32 (1), 59–82. Page | 41 Y. Ayden / EJEPS 8 (2015) 19-42 Yaprak, A., and Karademir, B. (2010). The Internationalization of Emerging Market Business Groups: An Integrated Literature Review. International Marketing Review, 27 (2), 245–262. Page | 42 European Journal of Economic and Political Studies 8 (2015) 43-60 Empowerment and Trust as Mediators of the Relationship between Transformational Leadership and Organizational Effectiveness Agron HOXHA* Department of Psychology, Fatih University, Turkey Abstract The purpose of this study was to examine the mediating role of trust and empowerment on the relationships between transformational leadership and organizational effectiveness. A total of 457 employees participated, 193 of whom were males, with ages ranged from 20 to 56 years. Participants were sampled from senior, middle and lower positions in the organizational structure. Significant positive relationships were observed between transformational leadership, trust, empowerment and organizational effectiveness. Hierarchical regression analysis found that trust and empowerment significantly enhanced the relationship between organizational leadership styles and organizational effectiveness. The results of this study support path-goal theory which suggests that different style of leadership needs to be applied to different groups or individuals in an organization. Key Words: Transformational Leadership, Organizational Trust, Psychological Empowerment, Organizational Effectiveness, Mediation, Malaysia JEL Classification: M5, M53, L20, L21 * Tel: +90 (546) 251 1034 E-mail Address: [email protected] Page | 43 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 1. Introduction Accumulating evidence suggests that transformational leadership plays an important role in enhancing the level of organizational effectiveness (Podsakoff, MacKenzie, and Bommer, 1996; Bass and Avolio, 1990; Yukl, 2002). However, there is little empirical research focusing on the processes by which transformational leadership influences and enhances the level of organizational effectiveness. Therefore, in this study, the researcher will emphasize on understanding the influencing process of transformational leadership on organizational effectiveness through mediating factors namely trust and empowerment. Past studies have reported positive relationships between transformational leadership, trust, empowerment and organizational effectiveness. However, there is insufficient literature investigating the role of trust and empowerment as mediating factors between transformational leadership and organizational effectiveness. Therefore, in the present study, the researcher suggests that trust and empowerment will add value by moderating the relationship between organizational leadership and organizational effectiveness. 2. Literature Review 2.1. Leadership and Organizational Effectiveness Previous research indicated that effective leadership is a major contributor to organizational effectiveness; leadership creates the business strategy that would lead the organization to success or failure (Bennis, 1987; Llewellyn, 2003; Ismail, Mohamed, Sulaiman, Hamran Mohamed, and Yusuf, 2011). Effective leadership will stimulate the right attitude and behavior among employees to enhance their performance in an organization. Leadership refers to the process of influencing others in order to achieve assigned goals in an organization (Yukl 1994; Fiedler and Garcia, 1987; Bass, 1985; Marturano and Gosling, 2008). Further, leaders are responsible to lead, direct, and coordinate with members to meet their expected goals (Burns, 1978; Fiedler and Garcia, 1987). A frequently used definition of leadership comes from the book “Leadership” by James Mac-Gregor Burns (1978) who stated that: “Leadership is the reciprocal process of mobilizing, by persons which motivates certain motives and values, various economic, political and other resources, in a context of competition and conflict, in order to realize goals independently or mutually held by both leaders and followers” (Burns, 1978, 425). Page | 44 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 According to Burns (1978), leadership refers to the stimulation of employees to achieve certain goals that leaders and employees expect. He associates leadership with leaders and employees together, not with the leader or leader activities alone. Effectively Burns shifted the main focus of organizational leadership from the behaviors and actions of individuals to the interaction between leaders and their followers as one group working towards mutual benefit (Burns, 2003). Thus, he made significant contributions to the schools of transformational and transactional leadership styles. Leadership style as compared to the general definition of leadership explains specific manners and approaches that a leader or manager uses to interact with others. While leadership refers to persuading employees to accomplish their tasks, leadership style explains the way in which a particular leader gets the task done. In addition, leadership style refers to the skills that the particular leader used to accomplish the task (Berkowitz, 2010). Depending on the type of work or different situations in an organization, a leader might exercise one of a variety of leadership styles. The two widely practiced styles of leadership are the transformational leadership style and transactional leadership style. In the modern era of a globalized economy, transformational leadership is reported to have strong influence on organizational effectiveness (Avolio, 1999; Ismail, Mohamad, Mohamed, Raifuddin and Zhen, 2010). The definition of organizational effectiveness varies from one writer to another as they look at different elements of organization, but they all associate organizational effectiveness with the achievement of expected goals in an organization (Llewelly, 2002). Organizational effectiveness refers to outcomes that organizations desire to attain (Bernard, 1938; Avolio and Bass, 1995; Quinn and Rohrbaugh, 1983; Zammuto, 1984). These outcomes vary from one organization to another, but their main desired outcomes emphasize product, financial performance and organizational performance in general (Yuchtman and Seashore, 1967; Denison and Mishra, 1995). Organizational effectiveness is reported to be the main focus of most organizations (Yukl, 2008). 2.2. Transformational Leadership and Organizational Effectiveness Transformational leadership occurs when employees are encouraged to meet the highly challenging expectations of the organization. Transformational leaders help employees find new ways to meet organizational challenges. The most frequently used definition of transformational leadership refers to a leader’s behavior, influential traits, power and situational variables that influence employee performance in a positive direction such as motivating employees to work more than expected and enjoy the work they do (Behery, 2008). Page | 45 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 Bass and Avolio (1994) identified four main dimensions of transformational leadership namely idealized influence, inspirational motivation, intellectual stimulation and individual consideration. Each of four dimensions explains the characteristics of a transformational leader in an organization. Idealized influence refers to the leader who becomes a model for his employees. In this dimension, leaders apply their highest moral and ethical standards towards employees or followers rather than practicing power and authority in leading followers. In modern organizations, employees are more skillful and they expect their abilities to be acknowledged. When employees are acknowledged for their contributions, it is more likely that they will reciprocate the behavior of the leader with respect and improve their performance. Inspirational motivation on the other hand, refers to a leader who gives meaning to different challenges at the work place. Leaders with this behavior inspire followers by providing meaning to followers’ work and effort. These leaders emphasize explaining the importance of their roles and performance to employees in the organization. This makes employees regard themselves as an important asset of the organization rather than a regular employee. Intellectual stimulation means leaders motivate followers by providing them with a variety of problem solving skills. This leader behavior makes followers aware of their intellect and skills that they have in solving problems or challenges in the work place. Followers need to be encouraged to express their thoughts and visions towards the organization and be taught to look at issues in different ways, thinking before acting and being accurate with decisions. Individualized consideration refers to a situation whereby a leader has a personalized relationship with each employee, paying special attention to individuals in an organization. In other words this behavior focuses on how to treat employees as your colleagues with neither prejudice nor doubt, and seeing a future in them. These four dimensions of transformational leadership transform employees from ordinary performers to extraordinary performers (Burns, 1978; Bass and Avolio, 1994; Behery, 2008). In other words, transformational leadership helps followers transform their behavior from traditional to new ways of thinking and be innovative in the working environment. Transformational leadership is interested in motivation, goal attainment, teamwork and behaviors that help employees find meaning in their work, and at the same time enjoy their work (Behery, 2008). Page | 46 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 Bass (1999) reported that changes and advancements in the marketplace and workforce over the last two decades had resulted in the need to promote transformational leadership more and demote the traditional style of leadership namely transactional leadership. Transactional leadership was more important in the past when employees were mainly driven by financial resources (Olanrewaju, 2009). Therefore, in the current globalized economy, greater emphasis needs to be placed on the transformational leadership style in order to break the old routines and energize work environments through inspirational leadership (Olanrewaju, 2009; Ismail, Mohamad, Mohamed, Raifuddin and Zhen, 2010). In this regard, Montgomery (1996) reported that: “transformational leadership works well when important organizational changes are needed because the environment has shifted and the organization needs to respond and break old routines” (p. 461). Previous findings suggest that the transformational leadership style contributes to organizational effectiveness more than transactional leadership (Organ, 1988; Emeryand Barker, 2007; Behery, 2008). It was noted that most of the positive characteristics of leadership such as encouragement, imparting confidence, acknowledging competence, motivating, encouraging innovation and many other positive behaviors are credited to transformational leaders (Yukl, 2006). However, the transformational leadership style is not necessarily suited to all types of organizations (Tseng and Huang, 2009). Previous studies have suggested that one style of leadership cannot be generalized as the effective style for all organizations and situations (Rad and Yarmuhammadian, 2006). For instance, in the study done by Obiwuru, Okwu, Apka and Nwankwere (2011) it was reported that in smaller organizations, the transactional leadership style was more related to increases in performance than transformational leadership style. However, the same study also suggested that organizations need to transit to the transformational leadership style as they grow. The advantage of the transformational leadership mechanism over transactional leadership is that it enhances organizational effectiveness by increasing the levels of organizational trust and psychological empowerment. Since organizational trust and psychological empowerment are well predicted by transformational leadership (Northouse, 2004), and trust and empowerment predict increase in organizational effectiveness (Zeffane and Al Zarooni, 2012; Goodwin, 2011), it is suggested that transformational leadership influences the levels of organizational effectiveness indirectly through the mediating effect of trust and empowerment. Page | 47 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 2.3. Trust and Empowerment It is clearly and consistently reported that the transformational leadership style empowers employees to express and practice their own creativity, which leads employees to develop trust and respect in their leaders (Bass and Avolio, 1995). From the literature we find that trust and empowerment go hand in hand with each other. Both, organizational trust and psychological empowerment reinforce each other and together lead to enhancement of effectiveness in organizations. Previous research has shown that psychological empowerment and trust in leader are directly related to an increase of organizational performance (Wat and Shaffer, 2005; Chan, Taylor, and Markham, 2008). On the other hand, when a leader trusts his or her employees, it makes employee feel empowered and confident (Goodwin et al., 2011). In addition, it has also been found that employee empowerment is reciprocated with trust in leader (Tyler and Degoev, 1996; Douglas and Zivnuska, 2008). It has also been reported that employees work harder if the employee is empowered and trusts the leader (Wat and Shaffer, 2005; Chan et al, 2008). Psychological empowerment and organizational trust are found to be essential factors to increase the commitment of employees and hence contribute to the enhancement of organizational effectiveness (Zeffane and Al Zarooni, 2012; Goodwin, 2011). Psychological empowerment means enabling employees with authority to make their own decisions about how to carry out tasks assigned to them. Also, trusting employees to do their jobs without constant monitoring makes employees trust their leaders (Kim, Tavitiyaman, and Kim, 2009). Empowerment gives employees a chance to explore and develop their individual skills. Trust on the other hand, refers to the faith and confidence between leader and employee. Therefore, in this study organizational trust and psychological empowerment are perceived as two mediating factors that enhance the relationship between organizational leadership and organizational effectiveness. When these two variables are present, the level of organizational effectiveness will also increase. The definition of organizational effectiveness varies from one writer to another as they look at different elements of organization, but they all associate organizational effectiveness with the achievement of expected goals in an organization (Llewelly, 2002). Organizational effectiveness refers to outcomes that organizations desire to attain (Bernard, 1938; Avolio and Bass, 1995; Quinn and Rohrbaugh, 1983; Zammuto, 1984). These outcomes vary from one organization Page | 48 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 to another, but their main desired outcomes emphasize product, financial performance and organizational performance in general (Yuchtman and Seashore, 1967; Denison and Mishra, 1995). Previous studies have reported that organizational effectiveness is the main focus of most organizations (Yukl, 2008). The role of trust and empowerment has not been previously studied in the context of that relationship. Therefore, in the present study, the researcher suggests that trust and empowerment will add value by moderating the relationship between organizational leadership and organizational effectiveness. According to House, Woycke, and Fodor (1988), it is the leader that must understand the needs and expectations of employees for their performance. Also, leaders must clarify to employees the expectations that leaders have from them. Therefore, House developed the path-goal theory aiming to enhance organizational effectiveness through effective cooperation between leaders and employees. The purpose of path-goal theory is to make clear to employees what to do, when to do it, how to do it and the consequences of their effort by providing them all necessary resources needed in the workplace (House, 1996). House, proposed four behavioral leadership styles as most appropriate to help followers succeed in their performance. The behavioral leadership styles are directive, supportive, participative and achievement oriented leadership behavior. House (1996) advised matching the leadership behavior with employee behavior and the work environment. The directive style is used when the leader must be clear and strict in giving instructions to employees. The purpose of a directive leadership style is mainly to reduce role ambiguity among employees in the organization. Directive leadership is useful when employees are given unstructured tasks or when employees are new and inexperienced. The supportive style of leadership describes leaders who provide individual consideration to their employees. Supportive leaders are concerned about their employees’ wellbeing and social status (Lussier and Achua, 2007). Leaders of this style tend to approach employees and develop friendly relationships between themselves and employees. The participative style is used when the leader involves employees in important decision-making situations. Employee’s opinions and suggestions are taken into account for decisions made in the organization (Yukl, 2006). This style of leadership gives opportunities for all team members to express their thoughts. In addition, participative leadership is team-work oriented and emphasizes close relationships between organizational members. Page | 49 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 The achievement-oriented style is used when the leader has high confidence that his or her employees will achieve their challenging tasks and look forward to continuous performance improvement (Yukl, 2006). Leaders of this style emphasize performance excellence and they are confident that employees can attain the expected outcome with the expected quality. Although, path-goal theory contributed in organizational leadership, leaders still find it traditional and not motivational (Hartog, Muijen, and Koopman, 1997). In addition, it is very complex to apply any of the four behavioral leadership types as it is difficult to determine which leadership style is to be used in which situations (Lussier and Achua, 2007). Therefore, House (1996) added transformational style of leadership suggesting that employees need more motivation and inspiration in order to achieve organizational outcomes. House (1996) proposed that with the inclusion of behaviors from transformational leadership, organizational performance can be improved. In addition, transformational leadership is reported to empower employees and develop trust between leaders and followers (Northouse, 2004). Therefore, in this study it is suggested that transformational leadership styles, trust and empowerment enhance the level of organizational effectiveness. The following hypotheses are tested. H1. Transformational leadership style predicts positive organizational effectiveness. H2. Psychological empowerment will mediate the relationship between transformational leadership and organizational effectiveness. H3. Organizational trust will mediate the relationship transformational leadership and organizational effectiveness. between 3. Method 3.1. Participants In this study 457 individuals participated, they were predominantly female (57.8%). Participants were randomly selected from different departments of a telecommunications organization in Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia. Participant ages ranged from 20 to 56 years of age, with a mean of 33.7 years. The majority (62.6%) were married. Educational levels varied across the sample, 29.1% of participants had acquired a bachelor’s university degree, a majority (32.2%) of respondents had completed a pre-university degree or diploma, and a slightly smaller number (30%) had completed 11 years of schooling. In terms of organizational level, the majority of respondents (70.7%) represented mid-level Page | 50 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 management and 27.4% represented non-executive employees. A small proportion of the sample (2.0%) comprised of senior executives. 3.2. Procedure Participants were randomly selected from different departments of the target organization. A purposive sample was selected using the selection criteria of participants being able to understand and respond to the questionnaire in English and in the ration of 1:2:3 from among senior, middle and lower management. The researcher did not have access to individual participants, therefore, a liaison person from the Human Resource department assisted the researcher to distribute and collect the questionnaires from their employees. The researcher followed up closely with the liaison person and was ready to help if participants need any explanation regarding the content of measures. 3.3. Instruments The questionnaire contained measures of organizational leadership, trust, empowerment and organizational effectiveness as described below. A pilot study was conducted prior to the main study to assess the reliability and validity of the measures using a sample of 30 respondents from a market research company. The final questionnaire contained the modified measures, details below, as well as additional questions to collect socio-demographic information such as age, gender, marital status, educational attainment, job position and work experiences. The Multifactor Leadership Questionnaire: MLQ Form 5-X Rater as developed by Bernard Bass and Avolio (2004) was used to explore the differences between transactional and transformational styles of leadership. The final MLQ scale that was used for the main study consisted of 23 items. The item-whole correlations for the final scale of MLQ ranged from 0.40 to 0.79, with Cronbach’s alpha of 0.95 which indicates high internal consistency between items. Trust scale was adopted from that used by Jarvenpaa, Knoll and Leidner (1998). The trust scale for the main study contained nine items. These items showed very high reliability and validity with the item-whole correlations between 0.72 and 0.82 and Cronbach’s alpha of 0.94. The trust scale reported very high internal consistency between items. All nine items were used for hypothesis testing. Psychological Empowerment was measured using the modified version of psychological empowerment of Spreitzer (1992, 1995b). During the pilot study, the PE scale showed low item-whole correlations and very low Cronbach’s alpha Page | 51 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 but the researcher retained this scale for the final study. It was found that in the final test the PE scale showed higher item-whole correlation ranging from 0.32 to 0.61 with Cronbach’s alpha of 0.80 which indicates high internal consistency between items. All eight items were used for hypothesis testing. Organizational effectiveness was measured using items from a scale originally developed by Denison and Mishra (1995). This scale measures the level and quality of new product development, sales growth, market share, cash flow, profitability/return on assets, quality improvement, and overall company performance. Item-whole correlations ranged from 0.49 to 0.78, Cronbach alpha was 0.92 which indicated high internal consistency and therefore no items were deleted. This scale utilized a 7-point scale, ranging from 1=Strongly Disagree to 7=Strongly Agree. Items were presented as questions such as “The quality of our products has improved” for the item related to quality improvement. 4. Results Table 1 below presents the means, standard deviations and correlations of the three variables used in the main questionnaire. As expected, the correlation between the dependent variables namely trust, empowerment and organizational effectiveness were significant. Similarly, correlations between transformational leadership and depended variables were high, as was to be expected with the previously reported results of good reliability and validity. The independent and dependent variables showed a positive correlation as well, which suggests that the higher employees scored in transformational leadership style, the higher the levels of organizational effectiveness. The correlation between empowerment and organizational effectiveness, however, was the lowest compared to the correlations between transformational and trust and empowerment. Table 1. Means, Standard Deviations and Inter-Correlations Variables M SD Transformational Trust Empowerment Effectiveness 81.96 14.18 47.65 7.87 40.30 6.02 43.57 8.26 TransTrust Empower- Effectivene formational ment ss 1 0.80** 0.61** 0.61** 1 0.64** 0.60** 1 0.48** 1 - Correlations are significant at **: 0.01 and *: 0.05 levels. Significant correlations were observed between the leadership styles, namely transformational and transactional and trust, empowerment and OE ranging from Page | 52 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 0.48 to 0.80. Pearson’s correlations indicated that the strongest correlation was between effectiveness and transformational leadership (0.61) followed by trust (0.60) and lowest with empowerment (0.48). The correlations between leadership and trust and empowerment were slightly higher compared to that between trust and empowerment and organizational effectiveness. Stronger correlations were observed between the transformational leadership and trust. 4.1. Socio-Demographics Analysis The results of one-way ANOVA were used to test the difference between different levels of Socio-Economic Status (SES) and the level of trust, empowerment and OE. No significant mean differences were found in gender, age and marital status. However, results from ANOVA showed significant differences between educational levels and job position with organizational effectiveness. However, no significant mean differences were found between levels of education and trust and empowerment. 4.1.1. Education Results showed significant difference between levels of education and OE. Significant mean differences in organizational effectiveness were observed between employees with secondary school and those with masters level education (MD=5.53). Comparatively, a higher significant mean difference was observed between those with diplomas and those with masters (MD=6.50) on the level of OE. There was no significant mean difference however, between those with masters and bachelors. The results showed that employees with less education reported higher levels of OE. Compared to employees with masters (Mean=38.10), employees with bachelors (Mean=43.37) reported better quality of OE. Moreover, employees with diplomas reported even higher level of OE (Mean=44.59) compared to those with bachelors and masters. In addition, employees with secondary school (Mean=43.62) reported slightly lower OE compared to those with diplomas but higher than those with masters and bachelors. 4.1.2. Job Position Similarly one-way ANOVA analysis showed no significant mean differences between job positions and trust and empowerment. However, a comparison of job positions and the level of OE showed significant mean differences. Tukey’s Post Hoc test revealed that there was a significant mean difference between junior executives and managers (MD=4.52) in organizational effectiveness. Page | 53 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 Compared to managers (Mean=40.05), junior executives perceived the organization to have stronger effectiveness. There were no significant mean differences in organizational effectiveness between the other job positions. In view of the significant differences, education and job position will be entered first as control variables in the hierarchical regression analysis. 4.2. Hierarchical Multiple Regression Analysis Hierarchical multiple regression analysis was used to predict how well transformational leadership style, organizational trust and empowerment are able to predict the level of organizational effectiveness among employees in Malaysia. Summary results are presented in Table 2 below. Table 2. Summary table of R-Square for Organization Effectiveness Independent Variables Education Job Position Model 1 -0.069 (-1.46) -0.039 (-0.83) Model 2 -0.107** (-2.60) 0.023 (0.55) 0.505** (12.35) Transformation - Trust - - Empowerment - - 0.07 1.60 0.202 0.25 52.26 0.01 2 R F-Statistics Model Significance Model 3 -0.055 (-1.46) -0.007 (-0.19) 0.202** (4.16) 0.225** (4.95) 0.332** (7.51) 0.39 57.58 0.01 - Numbers in the table are beta coefficients, and T-statistics are presented in the parenthesis. - Coefficients are significant at **: 0.01 and *: 0.05 levels. Overall, the results show that the regression model improved significantly in strength with addition of the transformational leadership style. Moreover, the addition of trust and empowerment showed a strong increase in overall significance. The first step of the regression analysis showed that the level of education and job position alone accounted for only seven percent of changes in levels of organizational effectiveness among respondents and the model was insignificant. The second step involved the addition of transformational leadership to the regression analysis which resulted in an increase in R² from 0.07 to 0.25 (∆F(1,453) = 152.50, p ≤ 0.01). The third step involved the addition of trust and empowerment to the regression analysis. From Table 2, it can be seen that with Page | 54 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 this addition, the R² value increased from 0.25 to 0.39 for organizational effectiveness (∆F(2,451) = 49.00, p ≤ 0.01). The beta scores for each variable are shown in Table 2 to reflect the contributions of each factor to the organization effectiveness. Transformational leadership (0.40) showed significant positive beta values indicating strong contribution to organizational effectiveness, thus, supporting the first hypothesis (H1). Moreover, the inclusion of trust and empowerment in step three lowered the beta values of transformational leadership, and trust and empowerment emerged as positive and significant contributors to organizational effectiveness. The results from Table 2 indicated that trust and empowerment did have a strong mediating role. Therefore, findings of this study suggested that hypothesis two (H2) and hypothesis three (H3) are both supported. In summary, results indicated that the strongest predictor of organizational effectiveness is empowerment followed by trust and transformational leadership. 5. Discussion The main goal of this study was to expand upon previous research in regards to the relationships between transformational leadership style and organizational effectiveness in the Malaysian context. However, the uniqueness of this study was to examine whether mediating variables such as organizational trust and psychological empowerment enhanced the relationship between transformational leadership and organizational effectiveness. Although, previous studies reported that Malaysian leaders in the past were more directive and autocratic in their relationship with their followers (Jayasingam and Cheng, 2009; Gill, 1998), suggesting that employees had little opportunity to participate or get involved in decision making. In other words, in the past, employee creativity and innovativeness was restricted and yet, this leadership style was reported to be effective (Ansari et al., 2004). In addition, Ansari and his colleagues (2004) have reported that in the Malaysian context, organizational hierarchy is well respected and employees are expected to obey the orders of their superiors. This type of relationship is against the practices of transformational leaders. However, in the current paper, transformational leadership showed significant relationship with trust and empowerment. These findings are consistent with those (Tyler and Degoev, 1996; Douglas and Zivnuska, 2008; Ismail at al., 2011) suggesting that transformational leadership increases the level of trust and empowerment among employees. The positive relationship between transformational leadership, and trust and empowerment indicates that Page | 55 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 employees are more comfortable with leaders who consider them more as colleagues rather than just receiving orders. Further, trust and empowerment showed strongly positive relationships with organizational effectiveness. In turn, the strongest predictor of trust and empowerment in this Malaysian organization was reported to be the transformational leadership style. Trust and empowerment also predicted higher levels organizational effectiveness. These results suggest that through trust and empowerment, transformational leadership increases the level organizational effectiveness. Therefore, Malaysian organizations need to pay special attention to establishing trust and empowerment among employees in Malaysia. Trust and empowerment are significant variables that enhance the relationship between transformational leadership and organizational effectiveness. References Ansari, M., Ahmad, Z., and Aafaqi, R. (2004). Organizational Leadership in the Malaysian Context. In D. Tjosvold and K. Lueng (Eds.), Leading in High Growth Asia: Managing Relationship for Teamwork and Change (pp.109-138). Singapore: World Scientific Publishing Co. Avolio, B. (1999). Full Leadership Development. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Bass, B. (1985). Leadership and Performance Beyond Expectations. New York: Free Press. Bass, B., and Avolio, B. (1990). The Implications of Transactional and Transformational Leadership for Individual, Team, and Organizational Development. Research in Organizational Change and Development, 4, 231272. Bass, B., and Avolio, B. (Eds.). (1994). Improving Organizational Effectiveness through Transformational Leadership. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Bass, B., and Avolio, B. (1995). The Multifactor Leadership Questionnaire (5x). Paolo Alto, CA: Mind Garden. Bass, B., and Avolio, B. (2004). Multifactor Leadership Questionnaire: Manual and Sampler Set, (3rd ed.). Redwood City, CA: Mind Garden. Behery, M. (2008). Leadership, Knowledge Sharing and Organizational Benefits within the UAE. Journal of American Academy of Business, 12 (2), 227-237. Page | 56 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 Bennis, W. (1987). Using Our Knowledge of Organizational Behavior: An Improbable Task. In J.W. Lorsch (Ed.), Handbook of Organizational Behavior (pp. 29-49). NJ: Prentice-Hall. Bernard, C. (1938). The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Berkowitz, B. (2010). Orienting Ideas in Leadership, The Community Tool Box. Chapter 25, Retrieved from: www.ctb.ku.edu/en/ (15.12.2012) Burns, J. (1978). Leadership. Harper and Row: New York. Lexington (MA): Lexington Books Burns, J. (2003). Transforming Leadership: A New Pursuit of Happiness. New York: Atlantic Monthly Press. Chan, H.Y., Taylor, R., and Markham, S. (2008). The Role of Subordinates' Trust in a Social Exchange-Driven Psychological Empowerment Process. Journal of Managerial Issues, 20 (4), 444-467. Den, H., Deanne, N., Muijen, J., and Koopman, P. (1997). Transactional versus Transformational Leadership: An analysis of the MLQ. Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology 70 (1): 19-35. Denison, D., and Mishra, A. (1995). Toward a Theory of Organizational Culture and Effectiveness. Organizational Science, 6 (2), 204-223. Douglas, C., and Zivnuska, S. (2008). Developing Trust in Leaders: An Antecedent of Firm Performance. S.A.M. Advanced Management Journal, 73 (1), 20-28. Emery, C., and Barker, K. (2007). The Effect of Transactional and Transformational Leadership Styles on the Organizational Commitment and Job Satisfaction of Customer Contact Personnel. Journal of Organizational Culture, Communication and Conflict, 11 (1), 77-90. Fiedler, F., and Garcia, J. (1987). New Approaches to Leadership, Cognitive Resources and Organizational Performance. New York: John Wiley and Sons. Goodwin, V., Whittington, L., Murray, B., and Nichols, T. (2011). Moderator or mediator? Examining the Role of Trust in the Transformational Leadership Paradigm. Journal of Managerial Issues, 23 (4), 409-425. House, R. (1996). Path-Goal Theory of Leadership: Lessons, Legacy, and a Reformulated Theory. Leadership Quarterly, 7 (3), 323-352. House, J.R., Woycke, J., and Fodor, E.M. (1988). Charismatic and Non Charismatic Leaders: Differences in Behavior and Effectiveness. In J.A. Conger and R.N. Page | 57 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 Kanungo (Eds.), Charismatic Leadership: The Elusive Factor in Organizational Effectiveness. San Frncisco, CA:JosseyBass Ismail, A., Al-Banna, H.M., Mohamed, R.N., and Pei, Z. (2010). Transformational and Transactional Leadership Styles as a Predictor of Individual Outcomes. Theoritical and Applied Economics, 17 (6), 89-104. Ismail, A., Al-Banna, H.M., Ahmad, S.Z., Mohamad, H., and Munirah, Y.H. (2011). An Empirical Study of the Relationship between Transformational Leadership, Empowerment and Organizational Commitment. Business and Economics Research Journal, 2 (1), 89-107. Jarvenpaa, L.S., Knoll, K., and Dorothy, L.E. (1998). Is Anybody Out There?: The Development of Trust in Virtual Teams. Journal of Management Information Systems, 14 (4), 29‐64. Jayasingam, S., and Cheng, M. (2009). Leadership Style and Perception of Effectiveness: Enlightening Malaysian Managers. Asian Social Science, 5 (2), 54-64. Kim, H.J., Pimtong, T., and Woo, G.K. (2009). The Effect of Management Commitment to Service on Employee Service Behaviors: The Mediating Role of Job Satisfaction. Journal of Hospitality and Tourism Research, 33 (3), 369390. Llewellyn, R. (2003). When to Call the Organizational Doctor. Human Resources Magazine, 47 (3), 79-81. Lussier, R., and Achua, C. (2010). Leadership: Theory, Application and Skill Development (4th ed.). Mason, OH: South–Western Cengage Learning. Marturano, A., and Gosling, J. (2008). Leadership: The Key Concepts. Routledge London. Psychology Press. Montgomery, V. W. (1996). Reinventing in the Public Sector: The Critical Role of Value Restructuring. Public Administration Quarterly, 19 (4), 456–478. Northouse, P.G. (2004). Leadership: Theory and Practice. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publication. Obiwuru, C.T., Okwu, A., Akpa, V., and Nwankwere, I. (2011). Effects of Leadership Style on Organizational Performance: A Survey of Selected Small Scale Enterprises in Ikosi-Ketu Council Development Area of Lagos State, Nigeria. Australian Journal of Business and Management Research, 7, 100-111. Page | 58 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 Olanrewaju, J. (2009). The Influence of Leadership on Employees' Commitment to the Nigerian Public Service: Implications for Organizational Effectiveness. Capella University, Thesis. Organ, W.D. (1988). Organizational Citizenship Behavior: The Good Soldier Syndrome. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books. Philip, M.P., MacKenzie, S.B., and Bommer, W.H. (1996). Transformational Leader Behaviours and Substitutes for Leadership as Determinants of Employee Satisfaction, Commitment, Trust, and Organizational Citizenship Behaviors. Journal of Management, 22, 259–298. Quinn, R., and Rohrbugh, J. (1983). A Spatial Model of Effectiveness Criteria: Towards a Competing Values Approach. Management Science, 29 (3), 363377. Rad, M., and Yarmohammaidan, M. (2006). A Study of Relationship between Managers’ Leadership Style and Employees’ Job Satisfaction. Leadership in Health Services, 19 (2), 11-28. Tseng, H., and Huang, X.Z. (2009). A Study on the Effect of the Degree of Optimism, Work Pressure and Work Efforts of Life-Insurance Salesman on Their Performance. Journal of American Academy of Business, 14 (2), 133144. Tyler, T., and Degoey, P. (1996). Collective Restraint in Social Dilemmas: Procedural Justice and Social Identification Effects on Supports of Authorities. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 69, 482-497. Spreitzer, M.G., De Janasz, S., and Quinn, R.E. (1999). Empowered to Lead: The Role of Psychological Empowerment in Leadership. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 20, 511-526. Wat, D., and Shaffer, M. (2005). Equity and Relationship Quality Influences on Organizational Citizenship Behaviors: The Mediating Role of Trust in the Supervisor and Empowerment. Personnel Review, 34 (4), 406-422. Yukl, G. (2008). How Leaders Influence Organizational Effectiveness. The Leadership Quarterly, 19, 708–722. Yukl, G. (2002). Leadership in Organizations. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall. Yukl, G. (1994). Leadership in Organizations, (3rd ed.), Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Page | 59 A. Hoxha / EJEPS 8 (2015) 43-60 Yukl, G. (2006). Leadership in Organization. (6th ed.), New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall Upper Saddle River, NJ. Yuchtman, E., and Seashore, S. (1967). A System Resource Approach to Organizational Effectiveness. American Sociological Review, 32, 891-903. Zammuto, R. (1984). A Comparison of Multiple Constituency Models of Organizational Effectiveness. The Academy of Management Review, 9 (4), 606-616. Zeffane, R., and Al Zarooni, H.A. (2012). Empowerment, Trust and Commitment: The Moderating Role of Work-Unit Centrality. International Journal of Management, 29 (1/2), 332-351. Page | 60 European Journal of Economic and Political Studies 8 (2015) 61-91 The ‘Common Sense’ of Austerity in Europe’s Historic Bloc: A Gramscian Analysis Ben LUONGO* Department of Government and International Affairs, University of South Florida, United States Abstract Euro-area efforts to address recession have moved Europe decisively into an era of harsh austerity despite budget cuts and other fiscal measures facing massive resistance from the public. Moreover, economists continue to express doubts concerning austerity and warn Euro-area officials that fiscal tightening only increases debt relative to GDP. Far from reflecting either popular or economic opinion, I argue that Europe’s pro-austerity discourse both reflects and is constructed by the hegemonic interests of transnational capital. Specifically, advocacy groups representing the business-finance community manufacture the ‘common sense’ of fiscal tightening within narratives of European profligacy and exploding debt. In reality, however, austerity only reinforces the neoliberal structure underlying Europe’s integration into the Single Market. Forces of transnational capital not only serve as the intellectual leaders behind this neoliberal integration but, as my research shows, work to maintain this structure by advancing pro-austerity discourses in a way that ensures their hegemonic position within the historic bloc. Key Words: Austerity, Europe Union, Finance, Gramsci, Neoliberalism JEL Classification: F55, G00, H10 * Tel: +1 (407) 733 3605 E-mail Address: [email protected] Page | 61 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 1. Introduction Euro-area efforts to address the current economic crisis have committed member states to budget cuts and other fiscal measures which has thrust Europe decisively into an era of harsh austerity. Bailout packages containing austerity provisions have served as the remedy for recession despite these measures facing violent resistance from the public. Even mainstream economists encourage more pro-growth policies under the premise that cuts in public expenditures do nothing to alleviate the debt while shortfalls of public consumption increases debt relative to GDP (Wolf, 2012; Krugman, 2012; Gros and Maurer, 2012). Regardless of growing skepticism and dissent from the public, however, austerity-politics constitutes Europe’s current finance orthodoxy. My research explains the triumph of the Euro-area’s pro-austerity discourse through a Gramscian perspective which frames fiscal tightening as an economic common sense imposed on Europe’s historic bloc. I build on previous research that frames European integration in neo-Gramscian perspectives (Cox, 1993; Gill, 1993; Gill, 1998; Bieler, 2000; Bieler & Morton, 2001; Apeldoorn, Overbeek, and Ryner, 2003) as well as other findings which identify the intellectual forces driving integration (Bieler, 2000; van Apeldoorn, 2002; Cafruney & Ryner, 2003; Holman & van der Pijl, 2003) in order to advance the argument of this paper: that forces of transnational capital have exploited their hegemonic position in order to manufacture the common sense of European austerity. Such a common sense reproduces the neoliberal order of Europe’s historic bloc as well as the hegemonic position of transnational capital within it. To accomplish this, I outline the role that the business and finance community has played in advancing Europe’s integration into a neoliberal superstructure. The EU’s neoliberal architecture reflects these financial interests which are pursued through the political efforts of powerful business advocacy groups who serve as the intellectual leadership behind Europe’s neoliberal integration. I demonstrate how that same political arm of transnational capital manufactures the common sense of austerity by exploiting the EU’s superstructure it helped establish. These advocacy groups accomplish this by framing Europe’s recession in apocryphal narratives of sovereign profligacy in order to build the case for restoring investor confidence through fiscal-tightening. Such an agenda which manufactures the common sense of austerity serves to reproduce the hegemony of Europe’s neoliberal project. Processes of European integration not only retool the state to serve the interests of global capital but, furthermore, hollows out its welfare capacity. This consigning of wealth and Page | 62 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 privilege from the citizen to the investor aids in reproducing the hegemonic status of transnational capital by choking counter-hegemonic efforts of labor. I begin with a brief review of the theoretical frames that have dominated the literature on European integration and underline the inability of these frames to conceptualize the role of social conflict in European integration. From there, I introduce the work of Gramsci who provides us with a frame to explore the discursive union between ideas on one hand and social relations on another and how this nexus shapes Europe’s historic bloc. The second and third section builds on previous neo-Gramscian literature to accomplish two tasks: The second section outlines how the EU not only operates according to a neoliberal logic but protects the finance orthodoxy from popular consent. States must follow a deflationary agenda, adhere to standards of Europe’s competitiveness, and cope with convergence criteria which place controls on public spending, all of which are imposed on states from supranational level thus removing it from democratic accountability. The third section discusses the intellectual leadership behind Europe’s neoliberal design and traces its origins to the efforts of transnational capital. In particular, advocacy groups, like the European Round Table of Industrialists (ERT), have exploited their political capital to embed discourses of competitiveness and investor-confidence in order to advance Europe’s integration into a single market. This all positions the fourth section to argue how manufacturing the common sense of austerity serves as a political tool for forces of transnational capital to secure their hegemonic status within the historic bloc. By advancing narratives of sovereign profligacy, transnational capital builds the case for austerity upon the logic of the ‘expansionary fiscal contraction’ hypothesis, which reflects and reproduces the hegemony of the same neoliberal principles underpinning Europe’s integration – those principles which call for promoting investor-confidence. Simultaneously, business advocacy groups advance discourses of labor flexibility to justify the shortfall in public welfare spending. Together, these serve as the intellectual justification for the business and finance community to lobby for further fiscal tightening. 2. Theories of European Integration European integration has traditionally been studied under two dominant theoretical frames: neo-functionalism and inter-governmentalism. Built on the work of Earnst B. Haas, neo-functionalism emerged in the 1950s to explain the integration of Western Europe through the expanding role of regional institutions. It frames regional integration as a continuous and self-sustaining process driven by the ‘logic of spill-over’ where the decision to place one sector under the authority of a centralized institution leads neighboring policy areas to be Page | 63 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 integrated as well (Tranholm-Mikkelsen, 1991, p.4). Because this integration is driven by a technocratic rationality, neofunctionalism doesn’t only assume the growth and importance of supranational structures but the incremental erosion of traditional state power. Inter-governmentalism brought sovereignty back into the discussion and asserted that integration cannot be fully understood without incorporating national interests (Moga, 2009). Andrew Moravcsik (1993) later proposed ‘liberal inter-governmentalism’ built on liberal theories of bargaining and compromise in order to explain how states, careful not to give up their sovereignty, may cooperate with each other over matters of common interest. Such prospects of compromise occur when processes of international interdependence encourage a convergence of national interests. In relation to the EU, this theory examined European integration in terms of a) how states’ interests are determined by the costs and benefits of economic interdependence and b) how negotiations are determined by the bargaining power of governments on one hand and the benefits of institutionalization on the other. While both of these approaches constitute an important body of research regarding European integration, they suffer from a major theoretical limitation. The focus on automatic processes of spill-overs or the economically constrained pursuits of national interests reduces integration to rational processes and ignores the role of conflict inherent in the formation of the EU. As a result, these reductionist frames analyze only the manner of integration rather than the political interests driving it. Marxists scholars have long recognized these limitations and understood that explaining integration in terms of political and economic conflict required incorporating the historical process of class structure. Peter Cocks emphasizes this point in “Toward a Marxist Theory of European Integration,” arguing that previous theories have avoided the historical and socio-economic dimensions to integration (1980, p.2). Because of this, integrationist theories were unable to analyze the social relations of production. Cocks therefore enjoined scholars to examine how open-ended class struggle shapes and advances forms of integration. From that point, Marxist research conceptualized both state and business as expressions of social relations in order to demonstrate how capitalist forces drove and purposed European integration as a market rather than as a political unit. However, Marx fails to offer a theoretical frame that recognizes the legitimizing role of ideology due to his belief that political and economic transformation is rooted in the crisis of capitalism. Understanding how market Page | 64 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 forces maintain hegemony, then, requires a closer examination of the intersection between social relations and discourse. Gramsci accomplished this through the concept of ‘common sense’ which entails “diffuse, unco-ordinated features of a general form of thought common to a particular period and a particular popular environment” (Gramsci, 1971, p.330). Generally speaking, common sense refers to popular but primitive accounts of how the world works. While these accounts may seem natural, they are actually historical acquisitions that have become taken for granted (ibid, p.198). Capitalism, therefore, presents itself as ‘common sense’ which produces the consent necessary to legitimize and maintain its power. Far from representing a peaceful unanimity, common sense serves more as an arena of contested ideas and represents the violent and turbulent front over the struggle for hegemony (ibid, p.422). Because hegemony is “grasped when the citizenry comes to believe that authority over their lives emanates from the self” (ibid, p.268), common sense functions not only as a material conflict but an ideational one as well. Hegemony, then, doesn’t signal only consent, but implies a precarious union between social forces as the interests of subordinate classes are partially addressed only to incorporate them into an historic bloc. Moreover, Gramsci speaks of the necessary role of organizing intellectual interests. For him, common sense does not simply emerge from disorganized interests but, rather, is produced with the aid of organic intellectual leaders who play an integral role in the development of the historic bloc. The goal of this leadership is to articulate the ideological justification for the legitimacy of the current system. However, their successful leadership requires not only articulating an ideology but, according to Gramsci, overthrowing the traditional intellectuals (ibid, p.10). In other words, hegemony requires the development of a dominant ideology and organic intellectuals assume the leadership position to articulate it. Unlike previous integration theories, a Gramscian approach provides us with a conceptual framework to examine the social forces that shape economic integration as well as the ideational forces which legitimize it. For the purposes of this paper, a Gramscian approach allows me to (a) describe how pro-austerity discourses reproduce Europe’s neoliberal political order (b) identify the intellectual forces advancing austerity as a common sense, and (c) explain how advancing austerity as common sense serves to maintain the hegemonic status of those intellectual forces within Europe’s historic bloc. 3. Europe’s Neoliberal Historic Bloc This section discusses the ideational dimension to Europe’s economic integration and, building on previous research (Cox, 1993; Gill, 1993; Gill, 1998; Page | 65 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 Bieler, 2000; Bieler & Morton, 2001; Apeldoorn, Overbeek, and Ryner, 2003), how that process executes a neoliberal agenda. Europe embraced neoliberal economics in response to the economic troubles of the 1970s and 80s which many blamed on government inefficiencies – stimulative tax breaks floated overseas in globalizing economy, Keynesian policies failed to address persistent stagflation, and regulations were blamed for stifling business and trade (Bieling, 2003). However, the most urgent problem in the eyes of public officials was what O’Conner (2001) calls the ‘fiscal crisis of the state’ where government expenditures for social programs and public services exceeded revenues from the tax base. As O’Conner shows, public officials shifted their strategy from raising revenues to a more market oriented approach of lowering taxes to attract business and investment. This is best seen in the European Commission’s 1985 report titled Completing the Internal Market which called for the dismantling of business regulations and trade barriers, easing the corporate tax burden, strengthening monetary cooperation, and other neoliberal policies. According to the document, such policies are evidently common sense given that “we draw the lessons from the setbacks and delays of the past.” (1985, p.4). The mention of “setbacks and delays of the past” serves to remind public officials of the ‘fiscal crisis of the state’ in order to frame government intervention as the cause of crisis. Proponents of the internal market believed that a more market-oriented approach would grow business where supply-side dynamics would obviate the need for a welfare state. Public officials, thus, called for bigger markets under the logic that more competition would create more jobs and more services. 3.1. Establishing a Neoliberal State This vision of the internal market was realized through the Single European Act of 1987 (SEA) which eliminated non-tariff barriers still remaining after the creation of the European Union Customs Union (EUCU). The SEA’s focus on market solutions are articulated in its ‘four freedoms’ of goods, services, capital, and people which “are enshrined in the EC Treaty and form the basis of the single market framework” (European Commission, 2008, p.20). This single legislative act dramatically transformed the EU into the market-driven project that it is today (Underhill, 1997, p.118). The EU’s neoliberal direction changed the economic role and power of both finance and the state. Finance exploded as neoliberal policies deregulated markets and reduced barriers to the movement of capital. This led to a shift away from commercial lending to riskier capital market activities. Simultaneously, Page | 66 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 competition policies denied states their traditional sovereign right to intervene in market affairs. This reshaping of the state, however, should not be characterized in terms of its shrinking – both businesses and consumers require a capable state to secure basic property rights, trust in currency, and laws governing financial transactions. Rather, the reshaping of the state serves to realign it with the disciplines of the market. This reflects what Robert Cox (1987) refers to as the internationalization of the state, a concept meant to explain how European states are re-oriented to serve the interests of transnational capital. According to Cox, the common feature of the internationalization of the state is to: "…convert the state into an agency for adjusting national economic practices and policies to the perceived exigencies of the global economy. The state becomes a transmission belt from the global to the national economy, where heretofore it had acted as the bulwark defending domestic welfare from external disturbances." (1992, pp.30-31) This is clearly evidenced in the Treaty of Maastricht which redistributes economic power from the state to a supranational arrangement of institutions that enforce and execute neoliberal policy. In particular, Euro-area members forfeit their monetary sovereignty to the authority of the European Union and are then subject to a deflationary monetary policy set by the European Central Bank (ECB) as well as competitiveness laws enforced by the European Commission (EC) and interpreted by the European Court of Justice (ECJ). For Cox, three developments are necessary for the internationalization of the state, (1987, p.254) all three of which are present in the EU. The first refers to the formation of an international consensus around an ideological understanding and prioritization of the world economy, which describes aptly the paradigmatic shift of Europe’s collective neoliberal turn. His second criterion, where consensus is hierarchically structured, presents itself through the consigning of traditionally state-based monetary power to EU authority. The third, and most important, criterion holds that structures inside the state are repurposed to translate the international economic consensus into national policy. This is evidenced in Europe’s competitiveness policies which thrusts member states into a race to attract business and investment by lowering taxes and relaxing regulation (ibid, pp.254-255). Probably the most effective dimension in establishing the neoliberal state was their voluntary sacrifice of monetary sovereignty which subjects Euro-area members to the real threat of insolvency and, thus, functions as a control over public spending. The fear of bankruptcy serves to justify the Maastricht Treaty’s convergence criteria [as outlined in article 10c(2)] which mandates that member Page | 67 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 states maintain budget deficits under three percent of their GDP and keep national debt under 60% of GDP (Treaty on European Union 1992, p.183). Additionally, the Stability and Growth Pact of 1997 imposes strict monitoring and penalty mechanisms in order to enforce the Maastricht Treaty which, by extension, attenuates the state’s ability to address joblessness or recession. The pressure for states to maintain a proper fiscal standing highlights Europe’s confidence in the expansionary-fiscal-contraction hypothesis, also known as expansionary austerity, a theory introduced by economists Francesco Giavazzi and Marco Pagano in 1990. According to the theory, a major reduction in public expenditures creates an expectation of lower tax rates thereby incentivizing higher levels of consumer spending. This in turn attracts finance capital and creates business which not only generate jobs but provides necessary services to consumers thus obviating the need for social programs. Additionally, the expansionary austerity coheres nicely with discourses calling for higher levels of labor market flexibility. A study published by the Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD, 1994) blamed Europe’s unemployment and slow growth in the early 1990s on inflexible labor markets. The report encouraged a reduction in welfare as well as curbing the efficacy of labor institutions. Despite little research corroborating the benefits of labor flexibility, the ECB published a report titled Euro Area Labour Markets and the Crisis (2012) echoing these same policy prescriptions. Specifically, the report called for major market reforms where increased labor flexibility serves as a “key ingredient” (ibid, p.10). The expansionary-fiscal-contraction hypothesis and labor flexibility both serve as the intellectual basis for Europe’s neoliberal order. Taken together, they highlight two important features of the Cox’s internationalized state: Expansionary austerity highlights the first where “Power within the state becomes concentrated in those agencies in closest touch with the global economy,” and labor flexibility highlights the second where “The agencies that are more closely identified with domestic clients – ministers of industries, labor ministries, etc. – become subordinated” (1992, pp.30-31). This not only transfers privilege away from the citizen to the interests of capital, but creates a hostile environment for labor; controls imposed on public spending trim Europe’s welfare architecture and shifts the cost of the Euro-area to labor while businesses extract record-levels of surplus value through increased exploitation. Page | 68 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 3.2. Preserving Neoliberal Hegemony Given how unfriendly the economic base is to labor, the historic bloc must work to legitimize its authority which requires embedding neoliberalism into all aspects of life where it assumes a ‘common sense’ status. Europe’s historic bloc accomplishes this through two processes. First, the surrender of a state’s monetary sovereignty to Euro-area authority removes neoliberal policy from democratic accountability and, thus, shields it from critical debate. Second, the historic bloc incorporates a social dimension in order to appeal to the interests of labor in a way that subordinates them to the interests of capital. The former refers to Stephen Gill’s new constitutionalism which refer to the shielding of economics from democratic debate. According to Gill, the aim is to: "…allow dominant economic forces to be increasingly insulated from democratic rule and popular accountability. Indeed, in neo-liberal discourse […] private forms of power and authority in capitalist society are only fully stabilized when questions of economic rule are removed from politics.” (1998, p.23) The historic bloc accomplishes this by consigning monetary responsibility from the state to the authority of the EU insulating monetarist and supply-side policy from democratic debate – which exposes the very real legitimation crisis within Europe’s historic bloc! The latter occurs through the incorporation of a social dimension in order to capture the consent of labor. According to Gramsci, those in the struggle for hegemony must cede some recognition to opposing interests in order to secure their consent. In his words, “the leading group should make sacrifices of an economic-corporate kind” (1971, p.161). The incorporation of a social dimension serves as such a compromise. The social dimension refers specifically to the European Social Model, which is an attempt to address the interests of labor and unions as well as marry social and economic interests. This is reflected in the European Commission’s 1994 White Paper on Social Policy where it decisively links social progress to discourses of competitiveness by asserting “the conviction that economic and social progress must go hand in hand. Competitiveness and solidarity have both to be taken into account in building a successful Europe for the future.” (1994, p.2). However, the values expressed in Europe’s social dimension are designed to advance European competitiveness and overall economic integration. Specifically, the European Commission places the quality of one’s social life in their contributions to economic life. In fact, the document makes a point of saying that Page | 69 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 it conceives of rights as they are articulated in the Community Charter of the Fundamental Social Rights of Workers (1994, p.2). This is best illustrated in the same 1994 White Paper which claims that values such as free markets, equal employment opportunity, bargaining rights, and individual freedoms constitute the primary ingredients for Europe’s social model (ibid, p.2). Subordinating the social to the economic has been a strategy pursued in other European institutions as well. A European Council document titled the Social Policy Agenda stated that “growth is not an end in itself but essentially a means to achieve a better standard of living for all. Social policy underpins economic policy and employment has not only economic but also social value” (2000, p.13). This was further echoed five years later in European Commission document titled European Values in a Globalized World where the EC stated that “it is essential to recognise that the pursuit of economic or labour market reforms is the pursuit of social justice; they are two sides of the same coin” (2005, p.13). The strongest push to incorporate a social dimension has been the Lisbon Agenda, generally characterized by two goals: to advance competitiveness and growth while achieving social cohesion and protection through European Social Model (European Council, 2000). The European Parliament’s Resolution on its Midterm Review of the Lisbon Strategy reasserted the subordinate role of the social to the economic when it spoke of social cohesion in terms of competitiveness and sustainable growth (2005, p.2). This point is reiterated by a European Commission communication titled European Values in the Globalised World which framed the possibilities for social cohesion in terms of states achieving low inflation and low debt levels (2005, p.11). The inherent tension between the economic and social dimension refers to what van Apeldoorn (2008) calls the “contradictions of embedded neoliberalism”. On one hand, the EU’s structure institutionalizes neoliberal economics which allows for a form of governance dictated by market forces. On the other hand, the social dimension attempts to bring Europe together and foster social cohesion. However, contradictions emerge while fostering both economic freedom and social protection at different levels. According to Apeldoorn, discourses of competitiveness remain hegemonic as they are protected at the union level while social cohesion is delegated to the states. While claiming to marry both economic and social interests, the historic bloc subjects the latter to the former as market interests are protected at the supranational level which undermines the social protections offered at the national level. Ultimately, the social dimension serves primarily as a process to embed neoliberalism by roping labor under a pretense of social cohesion. Page | 70 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 To briefly summarize, the institutional configuration of the Economic Monetary Union produces the hegemony of neoliberal economics in Europe’s historic bloc. The European Central Bank pursues a deflationary agenda while the European Commission and Court of Justice implement and enforce the historic bloc’s competitiveness doctrine. Coupled with convergence criteria which place budgeting controls on public spending, member states rely increasingly more on market mechanisms to provide services to the public and are therefore more disciplined to serve market interests. However, member states locked in competition to attract footloose investment sacrifice the revenues necessary for funding social programs and labor protections. Labor, then, must bear the cost of Europe’s monetary union as businesses extract surplus value through increased levels of exploitation. The European Commission implemented the Lisbon Agenda to address the concerns of a neglected social dimension, but Lisbon architects subordinated the strategy to the disciplines of competitiveness. All of this occurs outside the realm of accountability. Member states’ forfeit of monetary sovereignty consigns economic responsibility to technocratic authority which removes it from democratic procedure and thus critical debate. Consequentially, policies emphasizing deflation, competitiveness, and balanced budgets are simply accepted and enforced by political leaders who hold neoliberal policies as natural. Such a design of Europe’s historic bloc exposes the social purpose of European integration as a neoliberal hegemonic project. 4. Transnational Capital as the Organic Intellectuals According to Gramsci, “A human mass does not ‘distinguish’ itself, does not become independent in its own right without, in its widest sense, organizing itself; and there is no organization without intellectuals, that is, without organizers and leaders” (1971, p.334). Here I discuss the intellectual leadership behind European integration. If Europe’s neoliberal structure hollows out the state and exploits labor, then whose interests does European integration serve? Previous research (Bieler, 2000; van Apeldoorn, 2002; Cafruney & Ryner, 2003; Holman & van der Pijl, 2003) has demonstrated how such an agenda benefits of the interests of transnational capital. I build on this research to demonstrate how integration represents the success of the business-finance community in establishing Europe’s neoliberal common sense. Again, according to Gramsci, every interested group is organized by some intellectual elite (1971, p.5). This section, then, will discuss those intellectuals within the business-finance community responsible for embedding neoliberal ideology into economic, political, and social life. Specifically, I demonstrate how a networked and organized transnational class of Page | 71 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 executives and investors serve as the intellectual leadership who articulate the economic virtues of neoliberalism. The most powerful and vocal group in the business community is the European Round Table of Industrialists (ERT) which, according to its website, acts as a forum for major multinational corporations to lobby for the interests of the Single Market program (2015a). Their homepage proudly boasts the power of its business network by stating that it houses 50 chief executives of multinational corporations and that member companies of the ERT have a combined turnover that exceeds € 1,300 billion (ibid). More importantly, the organization flaunts its political capital stating that it is in close coordination with members of the European Commission, the Council of Ministers, the European Parliament, national governments and parliaments, business colleges, and the media (ERT, 2015b). It also states that it works closely with BusinessEurope in pursuing and implementing their political agenda. Not only does the ERT take pride in its ability to influence Europe’s political economy, but it sees no problem mixing moneyed interests and politics. In fact, the group argues that networking big business with government creates a synergy to inform business friendly policy. They state in a report titled ERT’s Vision for a competitive Europe in 2025 that: "A strong culture of cooperation between business, education and government should be expected.‘Revolving doors’ between the three sectors could create a shared understanding of the importance of entrepreneurship. This should permit the development of a common agenda, where workforce training, design of regulatory and tax systems and business development all reinforce each other." (2010a, p.3). What best demonstrates the ERT’s political power is the pivotal role it played in creating the Single Market. Then-President Jacques Delors of the European Commission (1985-1995) has publicly stated the influential role that the ERT played in its creation (ERT, 2015d). The group published a 1985 report called An Agenda for Action which functioned as an outline for the Single Market’s framework. Specifically, the European Commission’s White Paper that led to the 1986 SEA followed the ERT’s plan for a Single Market (ibid). Their push for the Single Market reflects the ambitions of a ‘double revolution’ which former ERT chairman, Daniel Jenson, called for in 2000. According to Jenson, the double revolution entails subjecting the state’s powers to the interests of the global economy while simultaneously consigning government responsibilities to the union level (Murphy, 2011). Their ambitions for Page | 72 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 a ‘double revolution,’ manifest in their efforts for the SEA, demonstrates the economic forces behind the internationalization of the state. The ERT is also largely responsible for framing Europe’s discourse on competitiveness. A major goal of the group is to identify issues of competitiveness within the EU and communicate specific policy prescriptions to public leader (ERT, 2015b). In a report titled Benchmarking for Policy-Makers, the ERT argued that the most competitive European states are those who can attract mobile capital which requires low tax rates, privatization, and wholesale deregulation (1996, p.15). This philosophy led to the creation of the Competitiveness Advisory Group (CAG) who serve as a watchdog group which reviews government policies and regulations against the standards of competitiveness (ERT, 1994, p.3). Essentially, the group is meant to secure competitiveness as a high priority on the EU’s agenda. Far from acting as an objective outlet, however, the CAG has actually housed many networked members from the business community including several executives of business members of the ERT. The ERT also shapes the interests of individual member states regarding competitiveness. For example, German Chancellor Angela Merkel sent an email to French President Francois Hollande and several ERT chairmen asking to convene and discuss the topic of competitiveness in 2013 (Merkel and the Dreams of Corporate Leaders, 2013). In fact, both Germany and France appointed ERT veterans, Gerhard Cromme and Jean-Louis Beffa, to serve as chairs for the Working Group on Competitiveness, a group tasked with recommending competitiveness policies (Press and Information Office of German Federal Government, 2013, p.4). Furthermore, the ERT has developed a system of benchmarking with the purpose of monitor competitiveness of EU member states and to make policy recommendations for government leaders (ERT, 2015c). This highlights the panoptic component of Gill’s new constitutionalism which refers to the implementation of pervasive forms of market-oriented surveillance. Specifically, these panoptic measures allow for greater monitoring and social control over the labor’s activity (Gill, 1995). The ERT’s push for benchmarking serves to bulwark such a panoptic architecture by way of monitoring and intensifying productivity levels of labor. This is essentially what the ERT advanced in their 1996 paper titled Benchmarking for Policy-makers: The Way to Competitiveness, Growth and Job Creation as well as their 1997 paper titled Benchmarking for Competitiveness. They also wrote several letters to the European Commission espousing the advantages of benchmarking. The group’s success in advancing Europe’s benchmarking panopticon is marked in the European Commission’s creation of Page | 73 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 the High Level Group of Benchmarking who, in their first report, suggested implementing the ERT’s agenda of linking the Commission’s Competitiveness Report to benchmarking activities (European Commission, 1999, p. 4). This report concludes by arguing how labor protections and government programs impede benchmarking efforts (ibid, p.16). Benchmarking serves the additional purpose to remove the politics from economics by making it a purely technical enterprise. This technical transformation was welcomed by political leaders, especially Portuguese Prime Minister Guterres who said that “The idea of a benchmarking system is to simplify the coordination of policies,” and “If we have clear strategies, quantified and verifiable objectives, I think the markets will respond in a much more coherent way” (“Europe’s Route to Growth,” 2000, p.10) Additionally, the ERT aids in the construction of Europe’s subordinate social dimension. For example, the European Council has made it a public campaign to fight youth unemployment, also known as the ‘youth guarantee’ which builds on an ERT initiative. The program works to make young people more attractive for employers by requiring governments impose structural reforms to education and job-training as well as increase vocational schooling (European Commission 2015). The European Commission claims to receive a lot of support for this program from the ERT (2014, p.59). In general, the ERT has been a driving force in advancing neoliberal ideology in Europe’s historic bloc. Their Agenda for Action served as an outline for the Commission’s White Papers which led to the 1986 SEA. Additionally, their efforts to frame the competitiveness discourse and to advance benchmarking have established the dominance of supply-side policies. 5. Austerity as Common Sense While the previous section discusses the leadership role of transnational capital in advancing Europe’s neoliberal ideology, this section demonstrates how those same political-economic forces frame European austerity as a fiscal ‘common sense’ in order to reproduces their hegemonic role in Europe’s historic bloc. The business-finance community’s recent push for fiscal-tightening follows the same logic reflected in the Stability and Growth Pact of 1997, which commits member states to adhere to convergence criteria as well as the Broad Economic Policy Guideline of balanced budgets. However, the austerity measures imposed on EU members following the 2008 financial crisis are historically harsh and mark Page | 74 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 a dramatic shift in fiscal tightening. Figure 1 illustrates the reduction of structural deficits as percentage of GDP. Figure 1: Reduction in Structural Deficit as Percentage of GDP Source: International Monetary Fund (2013), World Economic Outlook: Hopes, Realities, Risks. The severity of these measures is rationalized in apocryphal narratives of European profligate spending. Specifically, the GIPSI states (Greece, Italy, Portugal, Spain, and Ireland) were castigated by public officials and the media as excessive and indolent. For example, German Finance Minister Wolfgang Schäuble wrote that: "…it is an undisputable fact that excessive state spending has led to unsustainable levels of debt and deficits that now threaten our economic welfare. Piling on more debt now will stunt rather than stimulate growth in the long run. Governments in and beyond the Eurozone need not just to commit to fiscal consolidation and improved competitiveness – they need to start delivering on these now." (2011, paragraph 3). The language of “excessive state spending” serves as a retelling of the ‘fiscal crisis of the state,’ a narrative that blamed the state as the cause of the crisis in order to rationalize the EU’s neoliberal turn. Just as the interests of transnational capital served as one of the major political forces driving Europe’s neoliberal turn, they now exploit their position to advance austerity as a common sense prescription to Europe’s fiscal crisis. Framing the 2008 crisis in terms of debt, the ERT delivered a message (2009) to Page | 75 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 the informal European Council meeting arguing that earning the public confidence requires states reduce their debts by adhering to the Growth and Stability Pact as well as increasing competitiveness. BusinessEurope, another leading European corporate lobbying group, published a report called Combining Fiscal Responsibility and Growth (2010) which frames the issue in terms of “fiscal sustainability” and urges the policy officials to direct their attention to the issue of debt. This is, however, a false narrative as Europe’s crisis cannot be traced to a bloated welfare state. Figure 2 illustrates how GIPSI spending relative to GDP has remained well within the average ratio of other EU member states. Additionally, the fiscal conditions of the GIPSIs were actually improving in the decade leading up to the crisis. Figure 3 demonstrates how the collective debt of the GIPSIs was decreasing relative to the size of their GDP leading up 2008. Nonetheless, framing the root of the crisis in state spending serves to justify the historic bloc’s draconian embrace of austerity politics. Figure 2: Public Social Expenditures in EU in 2007 Source: OECD Factbook Statistics. Data missing for Bulgaria, Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania, and Malta Page | 76 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 Figure 3a: GIPSI Spending as Percentage of GDP Source: International Monetary Fund (2013). World Economic Outlook Database. Figure 3b: Average (GIPSI) Spending as Percentage of GDP Source: International Monetary Fund (2013). World Economic Outlook Database. In reality, the sovereign debt crisis is a product of the banking crisis as states dissipated large percentages of their GDP to rescue the financial sector. EU officials determined that reviving confidence in the financial sector was necessary even if sovereigns had to shoulder the cost. The popular adage, “privatizing profits Page | 77 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 and socializing risk” appropriately describes how taxpayers are forced to shoulder the cost of banks – which failed to properly assess creditworthiness – all to appease foreign investors. Such moral hazard demonstrates the privileged status that finance capital holds in Europe’s historic bloc. Additionally, the expense of bailouts incurred by the state creates the opportunity for transnational capital to call for further fiscal tightening. Leif Johansson, then-chairman of ERT, held a press-conference to send this message to state leaders before they met at the 2011 EU Summit in Brussel. He asserted that the Euro-crisis could best be addressed through “a quick and orderly return to sustainable public finances” (Schäfer, 2011, paragraph 14) and that this could achieved by a strict adherence to the revised Stability and Growth Pact. Of course, the Stability and Growth pact advances the logic of the expansionary-fiscal-contraction hypothesis in its call starve the state of revenues which, in theory, would boost consumer confidence and create an environment ripe for privatization. An ERT document titled ERT’s Vision for a competitive Europe in 2025 serves to communicate these interests to public officials in the form of policy recommendations. According to the document, these recommendations include respecting the Stability and Growth Pact with the aim of encouraging long term budget surpluses (2010a, p.5). Such surpluses are achieved primarily through strategies of labor flexibility. According to the report, budget surpluses “should be financed by cutting public expenditures on policies that are not sustainable” (ibid, p.5). They suggest that this be accomplished by reforming public pension plans, social security systems, and overall privatization. Specifically, the ERT suggests that member states “strike a better balance between social cohesion and financial sustainability, for example, by placing greater emphasis on patients’ responsibility for health care costs” (ibid, p.5). These strategies have also been advanced by other business advocacy groups like BusinessEurope who, in a report titled Putting Europe back on Track, called for reducing government costs through structural reforms to healthcare and public pensions while “promoting higher labour participation” (2009, p.3) Again, there are two sides to labor flexibility; the added risks imposed on labor relieves business of their responsibility to address basic worker demands. The ERT advocates for this in a report titled Flexibility and Employment (2011) where they argue that increased flexibility would create more jobs, smooth out employment transitions, and maintain corporate competitiveness. The report calls for specific strategies of “internal flexibility” such as reducing work hours of hourly wage earners as well as seeking “support from the workforce, social partners and public employment agencies, which can partially fund wage decreases” (ibid, p.1). Page | 78 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 Following such steps, according to the report, would allow “companies [to] maintain their competitiveness as the increased flexibility allows them to adapt their workforce according to market circumstances” (ibid, p.1). Additionally, the ERT emphasizes the need for a closer relationship between transnational capital and the state by marrying fiscal tightening with privileges for the business and finance community, a design that again reflects the internationalization of the state. For instance, after stating the importance of reforming the EU budget, the ERT’s vision for a Competitive Europe in 2025 argues that the EU’s Multiannual Financial Framework must avoid budget cuts in investment areas that promise future growth. This includes research and development which the ERT claims to invest more than € 51 billion annually in (ERT, 2015a). The ERT and BusinessEurope wrote a joint open letter to EU leaders again warning them that budget cuts to R&D would hinder growth (ERT, 2012). Additionally, the ERT has called for making it easier for the business community to have access to venture capital. They make these points in their report ERT Highlights, urging EU leaders to address “Europe’s structural weaknesses which included inflexible labour markets, low return on invested capital and insufficient R&D investments. (2010b, p.90). These strategies and policy recommendations constitute a pro-austerity discourse advanced by, and tailored to, the interests of transnational capital, primarily the ERT. More importantly, this pro-austerity discourse asserts the hegemony of transnational capital by embedding expansionary-fiscal-contraction and labor flexibility into the European Commission’s policy agenda. An example of this is a report1 published by the European Commission (2011) which argued for a single European core tax aimed to simplify corporate income tax systems in the EU. According to the report, this would “reduce tax distortions to investment decisions and increase opportunities for cross-border investments” (ibid p.16) which would make the EU more competitive in attracting capital. In 2012, the European Commission held a Competition Forum which discussed Commission Policies on state aid which opened with Vice President Almunia asserting that the most important agenda for the commission is “first and foremost, supporting the efforts that are being made across Europe to boost growth” (European Commission, 2012a, paragraph 7). This echoed the same 1 During the drawing up of the report, the Commission met three times in “extended formats” with not only the ERT and BusinessEurope, but other business interests including the European Business Initiative on Taxation, the Fédération des Experts Comptables Européens, the European Banking Federation, and the European Association of Cooperative Banks. Page | 79 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 sentiments of ERT representative Worlgang Kopf who also spoke at the function. The European Commission described the event as forming a consensus among the attendees regarding policies of competitiveness and state-aid. (European Commission, 2012b). Furthermore, the ERT and BusinessEurope, called for the Stability Treaty, or what activist groups call the ‘Austerity Treaty’ in 2012. Article 5 of the treaty would require states suffering from debt to agree to detailed structural reforms aimed to “ensure an effective and durable correction of its excessive deficit” (European Council, 2013, p.14). The two lobbying groups demand that “Voting rules should be strengthened to make it tougher for the Council to overrule the Commission’s recommendations regarding deficits” (BusinessEurope, 2011, p.3). The language of this treaty accomplishes the ERT’s double revolution first articulated by Daniel Jenson where national budgets are reviewed and approved at the union-level. What these examples show is that the ERT does not just call for more austerity on the whole of public spending, but designs an austerity agenda designed to hijack the functions of the state in pursuit of wealth accumulation. Another example of this is the ERT’s call to shrink government spending in all areas except research and development, an area that the group benefits from. The ERT published a joint statement with the European Research Council (ERC), an agency established by the European Commission, urging Europe not to cut its R&D if it wants to maintain its industrial leadership. According to them, “if we want Europe to be an attractive place for research, investment, and entrepreneurship, Europe’s R&D budget must serve this purpose” (ERC, 2014, paragraph 2) In 2014, The European Commission held an Enterprise and Industry meeting which they describe as an ”internal seminar conceived to keep our staff in contact with the frontier of research in economics, notably in the areas of industrial policy and economic reforms” (2014a, p.1). A presentation by ERT representative Roeland Van der Stappen showcased their benchmarking report which argued that the most important actions to take are to increase support for financing instruments aimed to aid SMEs with venture capital (2014, p.12). The report also called for increased labor flexibility by relaxing job protections and “Linking wage evolution to productivity improvements, international competitiveness and individual performance.” (ibid, p.25). Forces of transnational capital do not only influence politics at the regional level, but at the national level as well. For example, the ERT has worked in close coordination with the German and French initiatives pushing for austerity. The group delivered a letter titled “Restoring Europe’s competitiveness, growth and employment” to German Chancellor Angela Merkel, French President Francois Page | 80 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 Hollande, and European Commission President Jose Manuel Barroso (ERT, 2013). The letter warned the leaders against aid to national governments and urged that public money be used for ERT research and development programs instead. This again evidences how the group constructs an austerity agenda that marries government fiscal tightening with privileges for the business and finance community. Additionally, the letter suggested that businesses “link wage evolution to productivity improvements, international competitiveness and individual performance” (ibid, p.3) which advances labor flexibility by undermining worker’s rights and linking pay to business needs rather than collective bargaining. Later in March of 2013, Merkel, Hollande, and Barroso met with delegates from the ERT (including the ERT Chairman Leif Johansson). The meeting did not receive much attention from the media but President Barroso spoke at a press conference that framed the subject matter of the meeting in terms of austerity. He defended Europe’s focus on fiscal consolidation and insisted that structural reforms aimed at shrinking public expenditure are working. His most telling statement was his assertion that “growth indeed needs to come from increased competitiveness and productivity, not from debt creation” (European Commission, 2013, paragraph 6). He concluded by saying that “we have seen in the past that artificial growth fueled by artificial debt, either public or private, is not a solution” (ibid, paragraph 6), which is a statement that clearly evokes the ‘fiscal crisis of the state.’ The four leaders met again in 2014 as a continuation in their discussions on competitiveness (European Council, 2014). President Barroso introduced the meeting with a brief statement that emphasized the importance of implementing competitiveness policies as a way to encourage investor confidence. He reiterated that investor confidence is the “key variable for growth” and that a European recovery is possible with efforts of the business community (European Commission, 2014b, p.2). 6. Concluding Remarks A period of austerity may seem reasonable after governments dissipated large percentages of their GDP rescuing the financial sector. Even European leaders grow tired of austerity’s critics. In April of 2013, an exasperated Merkel said at a podium discussion in Berlin “I call it balancing the budget. Everyone else is using this term austerity. That makes it sound like something truly evil” (Barkin & Rinke, 2013, paragraph 3). However, spending cuts hurt some more than others, specifically those who rely on government programs offering education, Page | 81 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 health, and unemployment services. The fact that austerity politics is insulated from democratic accountability emphasizes this danger even more as those who rely on such public goods have no say in Europe’s austerity agenda, despite the fact that they continue to bear the costs of budget cuts in order to rescue the banks. Merkel’s statement reflects Germany’s will to pressure profligate spenders to adopt more austere measures. The reason for this lies in the fact that German banks would collapse without the current union. The irony is that France and Germany demonstrated more profligacy than the GIPSI states as their banks invested in Greek and Italian bonds while also investing heavily in Spanish realestate. This reemphasizes the point that the problem didn’t begin with public spending but, rather, with private lending and capital market activities. This reveals a nefarious development in Europe’s historic bloc where transnational capital hijacks those functions of the state meant to protect and privilege its citizens. In fact, Europe’s austerity agenda marks a new chapter in class politics where such measures function as trickle-up payment plans that redistribute wealth from the bottom to the top. This is best evidenced by rising unemployment rates in the GIPSI states (illustrated in Figure 4) while the richest investors in the world continue to rake in record profits while hoarding up to $31 trillion in international tax havens (Tax Justice Network, 2012). The crisis, then, starts and ends with the banks – though a bloated financial regime created the crisis, finance capital continues to exercise political power so that states both prop up and adhere to Europe’s neoliberal order. Austerity politics serve this function. Figure 4a: GIPSI Labor Force Unemployment Source: The World Bank (2013). Unemployment, total (% of total labor force) Page | 82 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 Figure 4b: Average of GIPSI Unemployment Source: The World Bank (2013). Unemployment, total (% of total labor force) References Barkin, N., and Rinke, A. (2013, April 23). Merkel Defiant as Austerity Criticism Mounts. Reuters. Retrieved from http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/04/23/germany-merkel-austerityidUSL6N0DA32N20130423#p1zGlsByI38FDB3o.97 Bieler, A. (2000). Globalisation and the 1995 EU Enlargement: A Neo-Gramscian Perspective. Current Politics and Economics of Europe, 9 (2), 215-230. Bieler, A., and David, M. (2001). Conclusion: Thinking about Future European Social Relations. In A. Bieler & A. Morton (Eds.), Social Forces in the Making of the New Europe: The Restructuring of European Social Relations in the Global Political Economy. London, England: Palgrave. Bieling, H. (2003). Social Forces in the Making of the New European Economy: The Case of Financial Market Integration. New Political Economy, 8 (2), 203-224. doi: 10.1080/13563460307171 Bieling, H., and Thorsten, S. (2003). Competitive Restructuring and Industrial Relations within the European Union: Corporatist Involvement and Beyond. In A. Cafruny & M. Ryner (Eds.), A Ruined Fortress? Neoliberal Hegemony and Transformation in Europe. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc. Page | 83 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 BusinessEurope. (2009, October 28). Putting Europe Back on Track: European Growth and Jobs Strategy post-2010. Retrieved from https://www.businesseurope.eu/publications/putting-europe-back-trackeuropean-growth-and-jobs-strategy-post-2010-presentation-marc BusinessEurope. (2010, March). Combining fiscal sustainability and growth: a European action plan. Retrieved from https://www.businesseurope.eu/sites/buseur/files/media/imported/201000765-E.pdf BusinessEurope. (2012, December 2). Business’ Plan for Reinforcing the Euro. Retrieved from http://www.iv-net.at/d3297/declaration_economic_governance.pdf Cafruny, A. and Ryner, M. (Eds.). (2003). A Ruined Fortress? Neoliberal Hegemony and Transformation in Europe. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc. Cocks, P. (1980). Towards a Marxist Theory of Integration. International Organization, 34 (1), 1-40. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0020818300003957 Cox, R. (1987). Production, Power, and World Order: Social Forces in the Making of History. New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Cox, R. (1992). Global Perestroika. In R. Milliband & L. Panitch (Eds.), Socialist Register (pp. 26-43). London: Merlin Press. Cox, R. (1993). Structural Issues of Global Governance: Implications for Europe. In S. Gill (Ed.), Gramsci, Historical Materialism and International Relations (pp. 259-289). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. David, G. (2009). Managed by the Market: How Finance Reshaped America. Oxford: University Press. European Central Bank. (2012). Euro Area Labour Markets and the Crisis (Occasional Paper Series No.138). Retrieved from http://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpops/ecbocp138.pdf European Commission. (1985). Completing the Internal Market: White Paper from the Commission to the European Council (COM(85) 310 final). Retrieved from http://europa.eu/documents/comm/white_papers/pdf/com1985_0310_f_en .pdf European Commission. (1992). Treaty on European Union. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Retrieved from Page | 84 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 http://europa.eu/eu-law/decisionmaking/treaties/pdf/treaty_on_european_union/treaty_on_european_union _en.pdf European Commission. (1994). European Social Policy – A Way Forward: A White Paper (COM(94) 333 final). Retrieved from http://europa.eu/documentation/official-docs/whitepapers/pdf/social_policy_white_paper_com_94_333_a.pdf European Commission. (1996). Benchmarking the Competitiveness of European Industry (COM(96) 436 final). Retrieved from http://aei.pitt.edu/3947/1/3947.pdf European Commission. (1999). First Report by the High Level Group on Benchmarking (No. 2). Retrieved from http://www.pedz.unimannheim.de/daten/edz-h/gdb/00/benchmarking-rpt1hlg.pdf European Commission. (2000). Communication from the Commission to the Council, The European Parliament, the Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the regions. The Social Policy Agenda (379 final). http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52000DC0379&from=EN European Commission (2005). Communication from the Commission to the Council, The European Parliament, the Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the regions. European values in a globalised world. Contribution of the Commission to the October Meeting of Heads of State and Government (525 final). Retrieved from http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52005DC0525&from=EN European Commission. (2008). Public Policies of the European Union. Retrieved from http://www.upm.ro/proiecte/EuPA/docs/carti/Public%20Policies.pdf European Commission. (2011). Impact Assessment Accompanying document to the Proposal for a Council Directive on a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (COM(2011) 121 final; SEC(2011) 316 final). Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/resources/documents/taxation/comp any_tax/common_tax_base/com_sec_2011_315_impact_assesment_en.pdf European Commission. (2012a). Competition Commissioner Joaquín Almunia announces modernisation of State Aid rules to strengthen the Single Market and boost growth. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/competition/forum/2012/keynote2_highlights_en.html Page | 85 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 European Commission. (2012b). Panel on State Aid control at a cross-road: Reform initiatives to strengthen the Single market. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/competition/forum/2012/panel2_en.html European Commission. (2013). Statement by President Barroso ahead of a meeting with German Chancellor Merkel, French President Hollande and business leaders of the European Round Table of Industrialists on European competitiveness. Press Release Database. Retrieved from http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_SPEECH-13-238_en.htm European Commission (2014a). European Commission – DG Enterprise and Industry: Economist Visitors Programme. Retrieved from http://www.unive.it/media/bollettino_ricerca/EVP_application_01_Call_668 6.pdf European Commission (2014b). Déclaration du Président Barroso avant la reunion conjointe avec le Président François Hollande, la Chancelière Angela Merkel et l'European Roundtable of Industrialists. SPEECH/14/144. Retrieved from http://corporateeurope.org/sites/default/files/speech-14144_fr_barroso_meeting_ert_19_feb.pdf European Commission. (2015). EU Youth Guarantee: Questions and Answers. Press Release Database. Retrieved from http://europa.eu/rapid/pressrelease_MEMO-15-4102_en.htm European Council. (1997). Resolution of the Amsterdam European Council on the stability and growth pact (No C 236/ 1). Retrieved from http://eurlex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:31997Y0802(01)&from=EN European Council. (2000). Lisbon European Council 23 and 24 March 2000: Presidency Conclusions. Retrieved from http://www.europarl.europa.eu/summits/lis1_en.htm European Council. (2012). Treaty on Stability Coordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union (T/SCG/en). Retrieved from http://www.europeancouncil.europa.eu/media/639235/st00tscg26_en12.pdf European Council. (2013). EU leaders agree measures to fight youth unemployment. Retrieved from http://www.europeancouncil.europa.eu/home-page/highlights/eu-leaders-agree-measures-tofight-youth-unemployment?lang=en Page | 86 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 European Council. (2014). Annotated draft agenda for meeting March 20th and 21st 2014 (5153/14). Retrieved from http://register.consilium.europa.eu/doc/srv?l=EN&f=ST%205153%202014%2 0INIT European Monetary Institute. (1995). Progress towards Convergence. Retrieved from http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/othemi/emiprogresstowardsconvergence19951 1en.pdf European Parliament. (2005). European Parliament resolution on the mid-term review of the Lisbon Strategy (RE\558893EN.doc). Retrieved from http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=//EP//NONSGML+MOTION+B6-2005-0186+0+DOC+PDF+V0//EN European Research Council. (2014). Joint Statement by the ERC and ERT [Press release]. Retrieved from https://erc.europa.eu/sites/default/files/press_release/files/Joint_Letter_ER C-ERT.PDF European Round Table of Industrialists. (1994). European Competitiveness: The Way to Growth and Jobs. Brussels: European Roundtable of Industrialists. European Round Table of Industrialists. (1996). Benchmarking for Policy-Makers. The Way to Competitiveness, Growth and Job Creation. Brussels: European Roundtable of Industrialists. European Round Table of Industrialists. (2009, February 22). Message to the Informal European Council Meeting. Retrieved from http://www.ert.eu/sites/ert/files/generated/files/document/2009_letter_to _the_informal_european_council_meeting_-_1_march_2009.pdf European Round Table of Industrialists. (2010a). ERT’s Vision for a competitive Europe in 2025. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/dgs/secretariat_general/eu2020/docs/ert_en.pdf European Round Table of Industrialists. (2010b). ERT Highlights. Retrieved from http://www.ert.eu/sites/ert/files/2010_october_-_ert_highlights.pdf European Round Table of Industrialists. (2011). Flexibility and Employment. Retrieved from http://www.ert.eu/sites/ert/files/generated/files/document/final_policy_do cument_flexibility.pdf Page | 87 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 European Round Table of Industrialists. (2012). Open Letter from Business to EU Leaders [Press release]. Retrieved from http://www.vnoncw.nl/SiteCollectionDocuments/Meer%20informatie/Open%20brief%20Busi ness%20Europe%20en%20ERT%20aan%20EU-leiders.pdf European Round Table of Industrialists. (2013). Restoring Europe’s Competitiveness, Growth and Employment (Ref. Ares(2013)332968, Final) Retrieved from http://www.asktheeu.org/en/request/427/response/1352/attach/5/Konecny %202012%201499%20annexe.pdf European Round Table of Industrialists. (2015a). Welcome by Leif Johansson, Chairman. Retrieved from http://www.ert.eu/ European Round Table of Industrialists. (2015b). About ERT. Retrieved from http://ertdrupal.lin3.nucleus.be/about European Round Table of Industrialists. (2015c). Competitiveness. Retrieved from http://ertdrupal.lin3.nucleus.be/working_group/competitiveness European Round Table of Industrialists. (2015d). About ERT: ERT Highlights. Retrieved from http://www.ert.eu/about-us#ERT-Highlights Europe’s route to growth. (2000, January 12). Financial Times. Retrieved from http://www.clintonlibrary.gov/assets/storage/Research-DigitalLibrary/speechwriters/orzulak/Box007/42-t-7585791-20080702f-007-0042014.pdf Eurostat. (2015). Total General Government Expenditures Percent of GDP. Retrieved from http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/tgm/table.do?tab=table&init=1&plugin=1 &language=en&pcode=tec00023 Freeman, R. (2010). It’s Financialization! International Labour Review, 149 (2), 163-183. doi: 10.1111/j.1564-913X.2010.00082.x Giavazzi, F., and Pagano, M. (1990). Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales of Two Small European Countries. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 5, 75–111. doi: 10.2307/3585133 Gill, S. (1993). Gramsci, Historical Materialism and International Relations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Gill, S. (1995). The Global Panopticon? The Neoliberal State, Economic Life, and Democratic Surveillance. Alternatives, 20 (1), 1-49. doi: 10.1177/030437549502000101 Page | 88 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 Gill, S. (1998). New Constitutionalism, Democratization and Global Political Economy. Pacifica Review: Peace, Security & Global Change, 10 (1), 23-38. Gill, S. (2000). Theoretical Foundations of a Neo-Gramscian Analysis of European Integration. In H. Bieling and J. Steinhilber (Eds.), Dimensions of a Critical Theory of European Integration (pp. 15-32) Retrieved from http://edoc.vifapol.de/opus/volltexte/2013/4320/pdf/s13.pdf Gramsci, A. (1971). Selections from the Prison Notebooks. Edited by Q. Hoare & G. Nowell-Smith. New York, NY: International Publishers Co. Gros, D., and Maurer, R. (2012). Can Austerity be Self-defeating? Intereconomics, 47 (3), 175-184. doi: 10.1007/s10272-012-0418-7 Holman, O. (2001). The Enlargement of the European Union towards Central and Eastern Europe: The Role of Supranational and Transnational Actors. In A. Bieler & A.D. Morton (Eds.), Social Forces in the Making of the New Europe: The Restructuring of European Social Relations in the Global Political Economy, (pp. 161–84). Palgrave. Retrieved from http://www.palgraveconnect.com/pc/doifinder/10.1057/9781403900814 Holman, O., and van der Pijl, K. (2003). Structure and Process in Transnational European Business. In A. W. Cafruny & M. Ryner (Eds.), A Ruined Fortress? Neoliberal Hegemony and Transformation in Europe (pp. 71–94). Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc. in ’t Veld, Jan. (2013). Fiscal consolidations and spillovers in the Euro area periphery and core. (European Commission Economic Papers 506). Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/economic_paper/2013/ pdf/ecp506_en.pdf Krugman, P. (2012). End this Depression Now! New York, NY: W.W. Norton & Company Merkel and the Dreams of Corporate Leaders (2013, May 3). Corporate Europe Observatory. Retrieved from http://corporateeurope.org/eucrisis/2013/05/merkel-and-dreams-corporate-leaders Moravcsik, A. (1993). Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal Intergovernmentalist Approach. Journal of Common Market Studies, 31 (4), 473–524. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5965.1993.tb00477.x Murphy, P. (2011, May 10). Austerity locked-in with EU Economic Governance Package. Retrieved from http://www.socialistworld.net/mob/doc/5324 Page | 89 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 O’Conner, J. (1973). The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New York, NY: St. Martin’s Press. Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development. (1994). The OECD Jobs Study: Facts, Analysis, Strategies. Retrieved from http://www.oecd.org/els/emp/1941679.pdf Press and Information Office of the German Federal Government. (2013). France and Germany – Together for a stronger Europe of Stability and Growth. (Number 187/13) [Press release] Retrieved from http://www.bundesregierung.de/ContentArchiv/DE/Archiv17/_Anlagen/201 3/05/2013-05-30-dt-frz-erklaerung-englisch.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=5 Schäfer, D. (2011). Industry warns Europe on competitiveness. Financial Times. Retrieved from http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/b904de8e-2afa-11e0-a2f300144feab49a.html#axzz2GmzeR1hN Schäuble, W. (2011). Why austerity is the only cure for the Eurozone. Financial Times. Retrieved from http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/97b826e2-d7ab11e0-a06b-00144feabdc0.html#axzz2gW1eOZcq Tax Justice Network. (2012). The Price of Offshore Revisited [Press release]. Retrieved from http://www.taxjustice.net/cms/upload/pdf/The_Price_of_Offshore_Revisite d_Presser_120722.pdf Moga, T.L. (2009). The Contribution of the Neofunctionalist and Intergovernmentalist Theories to the Evolution of the European Integration Process. Journal of Alternative Perspectives in the Social Sciences, 1 (3), 796807. Tranholm-Mikkelsen, J. (1991). Neo-functionalism: Obstinate or Obsolete? A Reappraisal in the Light of the New Dynamism of the EC. Millennium - Journal of International Studies, 20 (1), 1-22. doi:10.1177/03058298910200010201 Underhill, G. (1997). The Making of the European Financial Area: Global Market Integration and the EU Single Market for Financial Services. In G. Underhill (Ed.), The New World Order in International Finance (pp. 101-123). New York, NY: St. Martin’s Press. van Apeldoorn, B. (2001). The Struggle over European Order: Transnational Class Agency in the Making of ‘Embedded Neo-Liberalism.’ In A. Bieler & A. Morton (Eds.), Social Forces in the Making of the New Europe: The Restructuring of European Social Relations in the Global Political Economy (pp. 70-92). London, England: Palgrave. Page | 90 B. Luongo / EJEPS 8 (2015) 61-91 van Apeldoorn, B. (2002). Transnational Capitalism and the Struggle over European Integration. London: Routledge. van Apeldoorn, B. (2008). The Contradictions of ‘Embedded Neoliberalism’ and Europe’s Multilevel Legitimacy Crisis: the European Project and its Limits. In B. van Apeldoorn, J. Drahokoupil, & L. Horn (Eds.), Contradictions and Limits of Neoliberal European Governance: From Lisbon to Lisbon (pp. 21-43). New York, NY. Palgrave Macmillan. van der Stappen, R. (2014, February). ERT EU Competitiveness Benchmark. Presented at the European Commission’s Brown Bag Seminar for Enterprise and Industry. Retrieved from http://webcache.googleusercontent.com/search?q=cache:4vXw4sndTAJ:ec.europa.eu/DocsRoom/documents/4511/attachments/1/transla tions/en/renditions/native+&cd=1&hl=en&ct=clnk&gl=us Wolf, M. (2012). The Impact of Fiscal Austerity in the Eurozone. Financial Times. Retrieved from http://blogs.ft.com/martin-wolf-exchange/2012/04/27/theimpact-of-fiscal-austerity-in-the-eurozone/?Authorised=false World Bank Data. (2013). Unemployment, total (% of total labor force) (modeled ILO estimate) [excel data]. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SL.UEM.TOTL.ZS Page | 91 Page | 92 European Journal of Economic and Political Studies 8 (2015) 93-111 Islam and Foreign Policy: The Case of Qatar Turan KAYAOĞLU* School of Interdisciplinary Arts and Sciences, University of Washington, Tacoma, United States Abstract Qatar’s foreign policy dynamism has been impressive. The literature has overwhelmingly attributed this activism to Qatar’s desire for security through military alliances and soft-power. I argue that these claims remain incomplete and shortsighted because they exclude the role of Islam. I argue that the exclusion of religious factors is produced by these scholars’ unreflective view about the conceptualization of religion. This paper looks to develop a different theoretical perspective from which to look at the impact of religion on foreign policy. To this end, I use Jeremy Gunn’s conceptualization of three facets of religion—religion as belief, identity, and a way of life—to conceptualize the role of religion on foreign policy. I use Qatar’s foreign policy as an example to illustrate the problem of exclusion of religion in foreign policy analysis and how Gunn’s typology offers a richer understanding of religious factors on Qatar’s foreign policy. Key Words: Qatar, Foreign Policy, religion and foreign policy, Islam and politics, Middle East JEL Classification: Z12, Z18 * Tel: +1 (253) 692 5856 E-mail Address: [email protected] Page | 93 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 1. Introduction Since 1995 when the current Emir replaced his father in a bloodless coup, Qatar’s international activism has impressed many. The Economist praised this record, noting in 2006 that Qatar has a “[h]abit of punching above its weight, and in several directions at once” (A bouncy bantam, 2011) and characterizing Qatar in 2011 as a “Pygmy with the punch of a giant” (2011). These metaphors seem apt. Qatar has held a UN Security Council Seat (2006-2007), was Chairman of the Group of 77 (2004), hosted the Middle East and North Africa Economic Summit (1997), the OIC Conference (2000), and the WTO Doha Rounds (2001). The small Gulf country has diplomatically interposed itself, with varying success, in longstanding conflicts in Lebanon, Palestine, Somalia, Sudan, Syria, and Yemen. Qatarbased Al Jazeera’s extensive, if uneven (the network was largely silent on Bahrain), coverage sped the Arab Spring (Eakin, 2011). During NATO’s Libya intervention, Qatar provided money, weapons, and field advisers in addition to securing the Arab League’s support for the intervention. More recently, Qatar has successfully persuaded the Arab League to isolate Syria and then, subsequently, to impose sanctions. This international activism defies easy explanations. Still, three explanations abound in the media and academic discourse: Qatar and its regime are building alliances, are attempting to harness soft power for their own purposes, and, lastly, are motivated by domestic political concerns (Rabi, 2009; Kamrava, 2009). While providing rich empirical accounts of Qatar’s foreign policy, these explanations suffer from the over-rationalization of state action and the exclusion of religious factors. I argue that this exclusion of religious factors is produced by these scholars’ unreflective view about the conceptualization of religion. Rather than explaining Qatari foreign policies based on the role of Islam, this paper looks to develop a different theoretical perspective from which to look at the impact of religion on foreign policy. To this end, I use Jeremy Gunn’s conceptualization of three facets of religion—religion as belief, identity, and a way of life—to conceptualize the role of religion on foreign policy (Gunn, 2003). I use Qatar’s foreign policy as an example to illustrate the problem of exclusion of religion in foreign policy analysis and how Gunn’s typology offers a richer understanding of religious factors on Qatar’s foreign policy. This paper has four sections. In the first section, I look at the literature on Qatar’s foreign policy to identify instrumental rationality as its common assumption. In the second, I review the literature on religion and politics in Qatar to distinguish this literature’s emphasis on the structure of the political system from my argument that emphasizes the role on worldview, legitimacy, and public Page | 94 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 Islam. In the third and fourth sections, I propose an approach for studying religion in foreign policy, broadly conceived, by discussing three facets of religion—belief, identity, and way-of-life—on foreign policy of Qatar. 2. Existing Explanations of Qatar’s Foreign Policy: Alliance, Soft-power, and Domestic Politics According to the alliance logic, “Qatar’s geopolitical position underlines a systematic security problem” (Wright, 2011, p.128). Sandwiched between regional powers of Iran and Saudi Arabia, Qatar has relied on external actors for its security. With the British decision to withdraw from the Persian Gulf in the 1960s, Qatar allied with Saudi Arabia and founded the Gulf Cooperation Council in 1981, a collective security organization that arguably institutionalized the Saudi leadership in the region (Kostiner, 2011). However, Qatar has been seeking new friends in the post-1995 era because of deteriorating relations with neighboring Saudi Arabia, who had supported the old Emir, Sheikh Khalifa bin Hamad Al-Thani, Thus, the new Emir, Sheikh Hamad bin Khalifa Al-Thani has cultivated strong military relations with the US. Conforming to the Waltian “balance-of-threat” logic, Qatar has allied with a faraway great power to bolster its security against regional powers, namely Saudi Arabia and Iran (Priess, 1996; Lawson, 2011). American military bases cemented this alliance. Housing about 13,000 American military personal, Al Udeid and As Saliyah serve as logistics, command, and basic hubs for the US Central Command’s regional operations, including the actions in Iraq and Afghanistan (Ayoob, 2011; Blanchard, 2010). However, as observed by Cooper and Momani, “Qatari actions never followed simple alliance structures. Instead, as a maverick, it mediated and intervened in regional affairs where state interests were not clear and success was uncertain” (Cooper and Momani, p.103). Some of Qatar’s actions have diverged considerably from American goals in the Middle East. Qatar has developed close relations with Iran, financially helped Hamas and Hezbollah, and permitted AlJazeera to continue broadcasting what many American policy makers claim has been anti-American coverage. All these actions brought strong censure from the American policy makers. For example, Senator John Kerry complained in 2009, “Qatar . . . can’t continue to be an American ally on Monday that sends money to Hamas on Tuesday” (Cited in Blanchard, 2010, p.18). Defying the alliance logic and Qatar’s asymmetric dependence on American security guarantees, Qatar has continued to deviate significantly from American policies in the Middle East on issues like Iran and the Arab-Israeli conflict. Page | 95 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 Another explanation of Qatar’s international activism focuses on Qatar’s reliance on soft-power. According to this perspective, lacking the necessary material capability to defend itself against regional powers, Qatar—besides relying on the American military guarantees—has promoted the image of being a good member of the international community: moderate, responsible, and cooperative (Cooper & Momani, 2009, p.5). In advancing this image, Qatar has worked both sides of the street, so to speak, delicately cultivating a positive image in Western capitals and on the Arab street. Internationally, Qatar’s diplomatic peace initiatives, sponsorship of arts, culture, sports, and humanitarian aid have all served to polish the Qatar’s image as sophisticated, peace-loving, and humanitarian (Roberts, 2009). A variant of the soft power argument, “branding” emphasizes states’ conscious marketing-style attempts at crafting a positive reputation. J. E. Peterson (2006) and Cooper and Momani (2009) apply this logic to Qatar’s foreign policy. According to these scholars, Qatar has successfully re-branded itself by replacing the “backward,” “Wahhabi” image with capitalist, stable, and liberal (Cooper & Momani, 2009, p.103). In so doing, it has distinguished itself from its neighbors and achieved global recognition. In a similar vein, Debra Shushan argues that the desire for prestige explains Qatar’s international activism. “Qatari foreign policy is geared toward generating prestige, which the regime values as protection against both internal and external threats to its rule. Internally, the accumulation of prestige is designed to win public approval by enabling citizens to take pride in their country. Externally, the regime seeks to use its newfound prestige to insulate itself from expansionist threats by making Qatar an indispensible player in regional affairs” (Shushan, 2011). While plausible in explaining Qatar’s high-profile, prime-time news capturing activities, these arguments ignore the limits that Qatar—an authoritarian county with serious human rights issues in the areas of gender and foreign labor—faces in effectively influencing Western audiences. Namely, rebranding what essentially amounts to cosmetic changes may not create sufficient goodwill to overcome substantial obstacles (Rosman-Stollman, 2009). Qatar’s human rights record continues to be criticized by Western media, NGOs, and states (State Department, 2011; Human Rights Watch, 2012). A final argument explaining Qatar’s international activism draws on its domestic politics. From this perspective, Qatar uses its international activism as a means to ensure the regime’s survival. Particularly in the early years of his rule, Hamad Al-Thani used foreign policy activism and domestic liberalization to impress international audiences (Rosman-Stollman, 2009). Receiving approbation Page | 96 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 from the international community buoyed him against the new regime’s conservative opponents, mainly Saudi Arabia and its allies inside Qatar. As the regime has succeeded in consolidating its power, thanks to help from Al-Thani’s family, and in securing Hamad’s Al-Thani’s son as heir apparent, domestic reforms have significantly slowed down (Kamrava, 2009). While this argument has some currency for explain the faltering domestic liberalization efforts, it does not explain the growth of Qatar’s activism and risk-taking in foreign relations. The above-discussed explanations share a premise: the rationalist (utilitarian) approach to Qatar’s foreign policy. In this view, driven by a Napoleon complex (Shadid, 2011) or obsessed with a siege mentality (Petersen, 2006), Qatar has skillfully honed foreign policies (Lambert, 2011) and adopted a policy of “hedging” and “security diversification” (Wright, 2012) to ensure its or its rulers’ survival. This instrumentalist logic was taken as given because of Qatar’s endemic insecurity as small state in an unstable region and regime’s autonomy from any significant domestic constraints. For example, Mehran Kamrava argues that “As a small state in a rough neighborhood, much of Qatari diplomacy, including the country’s mediation efforts, is informed by a broader survival strategy that is aimed at ensuring the security of the ruling Al Thanis” (Kamrava, 2011b, p.556). Qatar has become the poster child for small states who manage to survive via strategic use of balancing and branding (Petersen, 2006, p.740). This logic is plausible; security concerns are paramount for small states in general and even more so for rich, small Middle Eastern states. International politics of the Persian Gulf is essentially security politics (Kamrava, 2011). According to this claim, Qatar is at the mercy of external help to secure the survival of state, regime, or both, and thus is constantly strategizing. When such material explanations fail, many scholars invoke branding: For example, just after reducing Qatar’s foreign policy to survival instinct, Mehran Kamrava argues that, “Mediation has emerged as one of the central tools for enhancing Qatari soft power and global image” (Kamrava, 2011, p.556). This premise reduces Qatar’s foreign policy to logical of expected consequences. Uzi Rabi’s description of Qatar’s foreign policy regarding Israel illustrates this tendency: Qatar “skillfully generate[s] a sophisticated, independent foreign policy agenda that differentiates itself from larger and influential neighbors, while simultaneously upgrading its international profile and gaining regional prominence” (Rabi, 2009, p.443). In this highly sophisticated hedging strategy, Qatar carefully calculates a payoff curve for any action. “Qatar has used both normalization with and estrangement from Israel as policy tools, calibrated to maintain its visibility in a constantly changing geopolitical environment. Qatar has deemed normalization with Israel as a calculated risk through which to Page | 97 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 promote its broader foreign policy objectives” (Rabi, 2009, p.459). According to this rationalist view, which reduces Qatar’s diplomacy to a series of actions based purely on cost-benefit calculations the logic and processes of Qatar’s foreign policy differs little from the Qatar Investment Authority’s decisions. This logic of expected consequences leaves no room for the culture and religion play any role on Qatar’s foreign policy. According to this logic, since Qatari rulers almost always treat non-security related concerns secondarily to—and usually in service of—ensuring Qatar’s perpetually threatened security, any Qatari international activism can be reduced to its security needs. The absence of culture and religion is even more surprising because Islam is fully ingrained into Qatar’s history and society. This is a striking loss of perspective and explanatory power. Apart from Saudi Arabia, Qatar is the only place where the conservative HanballiWahhabi understanding of Islam holds sway; Qatar’s legal system is partially based on Shari’a; and Qatar is officially identified as an Islamic state. Arguing that Islam does not have any significant influence on Qatar’s foreign policy is similar to the argument that political liberalism does not have any significant influence on American foreign policy. This exclusively rationalist approach, which discounts the impact of Islam on Qatar’s foreign policy, resonates well with other empirical studies on the foreign policies of Muslim-majority states. While scholars of religion and politics have demonstrated religion’s growing importance in domestic and international politics, the literature on Islam and foreign policy has suggested only an ambiguous—often epiphenomenal—role for Islam in the foreign relations of Muslim-majority states. Even these scholars who concede that Islam has a moral system shape the values, norms, and principles of a society, constitute an important part of state identity, and in many cases establish the backbone of regime’s legitimacy, if it has a place in foreign policy of Muslim states, it is an instrumental one (Shaffer, 2006). Brenda Shaffer for example argues that “assuming all things are equal, culture can be assumed to play a role in foreign policy decision making. All things are not equal. . .” (2006, p.1). Although states and ruling regimes invoke Islam rhetorically to justify their foreign policies, but when necessary they decouple rhetoric and policies. Paradoxically, only other states “take their rhetoric seriously” (2006, p.6). Even in ‘Islamic’ states, “Islam does not necessarily limit foreign policy options” (2006, p.4). Because Muslim rulers often define what Islamic requires a particular conjecture and justify their “pro-Western policies by creating a distinction between the dictates of ‘good Islam’ or ‘real Islam,’ and ‘bad Islam’ or ‘false Islam’” (2006, p.5). Page | 98 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 Ironically, a casual review of this literature even suggests that religion may have more influence on American foreign policy than on Qatar’s foreign policy. This counterintuitive suggestion is in part an artifact of the literature’s emphasis on rulers’ sensitivity to constituencies’ demands. This factor is arguably lacking in Qatar, thus leaving its rulers isolated from interest group pressure (Henne, 2011). Reading the scholarship in this manner, the reader notes that Qatar’s rulers are largely unconstrained by the public and mindful of pressing security concerns; they thus override any concern—including that of religion—in service of state survival when crafting Qatar’s foreign policy. Yet this approach, endemic in foreign policy of Muslim states’ literature, contradicts much of the current international relations literature that has increasingly downplayed the effect of the logic of expected consequences in international relations while underscoring the non-deliberative, reflective factors, including norms, ideas, and identities, habits on state actions (Wendt, 1999; Pouliot, 2008; Hopf, 2012). 3. Bringing Islam into Debates about Qatar’s Foreign Polices Following Gunn (2003), I propose three ways of thinking about Islam’s influence on foreign policy: Islam as belief, identity, and a way-of-life, which I call the three cuts. Each cut moves further away from rationalist thinking endemic in scholarship on Qatar’s foreign policy and from the instrumentalist and essentialist approach to religion. Each cut also requires the use of political, sociological, and ethnographic methods and requiring a shift from thinking of religion as a causal to constitutive factor on foreign policy. 3.1. First Cut: Religion as Belief and the effect of Political Islam on Qatar’s Foreign Policy This first cut treats religion as a belief in a set of doctrines about salvation, Godhead, and angels. Religion binds believers to these doctrines. The extension of this logic to foreign policy often invokes “doctrines” that may have political implications, such as dar-ul Islam versus dar-ul harb, the primacy of umma (Muslim solidarity) over nation-states, and the Sunni doctrine of Caliphate. In domestic politics, these religion-based political beliefs are represented by either political Islamists or safeguarded by state bureaucracy and institutions in “Islamist” states. Parallel to their powers in domestic politics, these groups and institutions exert influence on decision-makers to shape the state’s foreign policy. Qatar’s case illustrates the limited value in conceptualizing the role of religion on foreign policy in the form of political Islam. Unlike many other nations in the Middle East, Islam as a political force has played only a marginal role in the Qatari Page | 99 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 political system. Historical, institutional, and political reasons account for this minor role in Qatar’s domestic and foreign policy. Historically, unlike Saudi Arabia, where religious (Wahhabis, in particular) and political forces (the Saudi tribe) were intertwined in the state-building process, the Al-Thani family, who moved into the Qatar peninsula in the 1800s, has single-handedly built Qatar’s contemporary structure (Fromherz, 2012). Until recently, Qatar, dotted by small fishing and pearling villages and lacking in urban centers, did not attract religious scholars or leaders. Consequently, Qatari state rulers have “imported” imams and preachers, initially from Saudi Arabia. As relations with the Saudis soured in the 1990s, the Qatari government has increasingly recruited Egyptians, Yemenis, Syrians, and Iraqis. These temporary religious workers lack a strong social and political base to mobilize the society for political demands. Moreover, the possibility of summary deportation and the consequent loss of salary serve as a significant deterrent for any unsanctioned political activism on the part of the foreign imams (Kamrava, 2009, p.410). Institutionally, the religious “sector” does not have strong representation in the government. Although the government established a Ministry for Islamic Affairs and Endowments (Awqaf) in 1993, in terms of power and prestige, Awqaf is more similar to Turkey’s Directorate of Religious Affairs than the powerful office of Saudi Arabia’s Grand Mufti (Baskan & Wright, 2010, p.99). In fact, Awqaf was not established until nearly a quarter century after Qatari independence. While Awqaf has brought some religious perspective, promoting the government to adopt Islamic-inspired policies, the overall role of Awqaf has been limited to concerns surrounding religious services. For example, it has no role in shaping the education curriculum (Baskan & Wright, 2010, p.109). Unlike the Saudi King, the Qatar’s Emir does not seek fatwas to justify his policies. Politically, the Al-Thanis, who have controlled the government with few, if any, domestic constrains from the outset, do not want to share their power. The revenue from oil and natural gas has allowed the Al-Thanis to create a “classic rentier state” (Fromherz, 2012, p.111). The government provides major services without taxation and in return rejects any meaningful public participation. In other words, the Qatari government does not depend on the support of any domestic religious actor in order to maintain its rule. Facing little domestic resistance, the rulers have the latitude to develop a foreign policy that advances their interests. All these factors marginalize the religious influence on politics in Qatar. Baskan and Wright even argue that “at a political level, Qatar has a secular character more comparable to Turkey than Saudi Arabia” (Baskan & Wright, 2010, Page | 100 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 p.108). Yet, as discussed by these authors, there are signs that things may be changing: increasing democratic reforms may bring stronger religious voices to the government; the population growth may necessitate Al-Thani family to use religion to strengthen social cohesion; and growing indigenous ulama (religious scholars) within Qatari society may be more influential in advancing a “greater role of religion at a political and societal level” (Baskan & Wright, 2010, p.96). There are also two additional ways in which political Islam may influence Qatari politics. Several scholars, however, have discussed the role of informal, personal links in Qatari politics within the context of religion (Foley, 2010). These connections are significant because “the politics of foreign policy tends to be far more personalized in Arab states of the Persian Gulf than in most other states, and, typically involves only a small number of elites” (Wright, 2011b, p.78). Foley, for example, points to several “well-known Islamist supporters” within the ruling elite, such as the fomer Interior Minister, Shaykh Abdallah bin Khalifa Al-Thani, and the Emir’s second-oldest son, Shaykh Fahd bin Hamad Al-Thani (Foley, 2010; Blanchard, 2010, pp.15-16). Moreover, Qatar has accepted several high profile religious exiles. Notably, Shaykh Abdullah bin Zayd al-Mahmud, a Hanballi-Wahhabi scholar from Saudi Arabia who was exiled following the seizure of the Grand Mosque in Mecca in 1979, lives in Qatar. There is also Yusuf al-Qaradawi. Exiled from Egypt in the early 1960s, he has settled in Qatar. His writings, including The Lawful and the Prohibited in Islam, and his appearances on talk shows like Sharia and Life have been widely watched throughout the Muslim world. His deep connections to the Muslim Brotherhood and his respected position among the Qatari elite have allowed him to establish an informal network between the Islamists and Qatari rulers (Kamrava, 2009). It was suggested that Qaradawi has privileged access and considerable influence on Emir (Barakata, 2012) and brokered connections between Qatari government and high-profile Muslim Brootherhood figures like Tunisian Rachid al-Ghannouchi. These informal—yet strong—ties to the Muslim Brotherhood and to its various incarnations in Libya, Syria, Tunisia, and Palestine have propelled Qatar in a unique position among the rulers in the Muslim world. As a result of such connections, the Qatari rulers were positively disposed toward the Arab Spring and the role of Islamists in the various protests. Whether the subject is formal or informal relations, the discussion in the literature has focused on the effects of “political Islam”—discernible political ideas informed by “Islam” and advanced in formal institutions or through informal channels by a clearly identifiable religiously oriented individual or group. In this view, the impact of religion on foreign policy practices corresponds to the Page | 101 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 institutional or political clout of religious leaders, movements, and bureaucracies. In a way, focusing on the institutional role of religion is still an effect of the salience of over-rationalization in political science literature on religion. It assumes that power can only come through political institutions, as opposed to a more cultural impact. Looking solely at “who has power”, like the security scholars will, misses the importance of religion on Qatari foreign policy if this influence is grounded in identity, legitimacy and everyday practices. Overall, this approach, which is a conventional one in political science discussions concerning religion and politics, allows a minor role for religious influences in Qatari politics as well as in foreign policy. When skeptics dismiss the role of religion on foreign policy, they largely focus on this type of religious influence. 3.2. Second Cut: Islamic Identity and Legitimacy on Qatar’s Foreign Policy The second facet of religion is identity. Religion binds the believer to a community more than to a set of doctrines. According to this view, similar to ethnic and racial identity, people are born into religion rather than believe it through inner convictions and even an agnostic Muslim may still be part of the Muslim umma. Foreign policy is then a reflection of this collective identity that highlights shared culture, history, and traditions more than shared creeds, doctrines, or theology. Religion as identity focuses on constitutive rather than strictly causal role of religion on foreign policy. In this view, religion can influence foreign policy through shaping identity of policy makers, their constituencies, or their audience. Religion is one of the many factors informing the identity of a policymaker and difficult to measure its effect on other factors, but its power often shape actors’ interpretation of the international relations and dispose the policymakers to pursue some policies rather than others. Identities are always social and relational and were shaped with interactions of other actors (Wendt, 1999). Identity can also be part of cultural and ideological underpinning of the society and informs and conditions the foreign policies. Constructivist international relations scholars’ conceptualizations of state identity provide some insights for this understanding of state identity that has been overlook on studies about Qatar’s foreign policy. Telhami and Barnett define identity is “the understanding of oneself in relations to others. Identities, in short, are not only personal or psychological, but are also social, profoundly influenced by the actor’s interaction and the relationship to others” (Telhami & Barnett, 2002, p.8). They argue that state identity—corporate and officially demarcated identity linked to the state apparatus—and national identity have significant effect on state’s foreign policy. These identities are in turn shaped by political elites, social forces, and international forces. Page | 102 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 The state and national identity’s role on foreign policy is constitutive rather than causal. While in some instances one can establish a direct link between identity and behavior, identity mostly works by predisposing the state to follow particular behavior or make certain other behavior less likely. “To say that the shift in Egypt’s identity from Arabist to statist made possible the Camp David accords is not to say that all Arab states with a statist identity will make peace with Israel. Rather, the Arab identity as previous inscribed had treated peace with Israel as nearly taboo, and the shift toward a state-national identity made peaces with Israel thinkable” (Telhami & Barnett, 2002, p.18). Jordan’s embrace of Jordanian identity made it easier to give up its claim on the West Bank. “To say that an Islamic identity makes an alliance with the West difficult is not to say that it is inconceivable.” (2002, p.18). For example it is often the case that states often act to intervene on the behalf of their co-religions or they tend to provide them more humanitarian aid. For example while Qatar also provided disaster relief to America after Katrina and Japan after Tsunami, the overwhelming majority of its foreign aid goes to Muslim nations. Qatar’s mediation exclusively focused on problems of the Muslim societies. Religion also shapes the identity and worldview of the rulers’ constituencies who expect that rulers would not act counter to widespread preferences of the society. Islam underpins the legitimacy of the Qatari rulers’ claim to authority (Wright, 2011, p.83). In Qatar and other more religiously based states, legitimacy is not merely legal-rational authority, but also – and perhaps more primarily – traditional authority. “In many respects, Islamic identity and the upholding of its virtues is uniformly linked to legitimacy of the governments and ruling elites” (Wright, 2009, p.76). The Qatar state also adopted Islam as official state identity. This is codified in the first article of Qatar’s Constitution: “Qatar is an independent Arab state. Islam is the State’s religion and the Islamic Shariah is the main source of its legislations. It has a democratic political system. Its official language is Arabic. People of Qatar are part of the Arab nation (ummah).” (Constitution of Qatar, 2004) While rulers have extensive autonomy to craft the country’s foreign policy in Qatar, the rulers would hesitate to take any major foreign policy decisions that may undermine the regime’s legitimacy, “the normative belief by an actor that a rule or institution ought to be obeyed” (Hurd, 1999, p.381). “Religion can lend legitimacy to governments as well as specific policies followed by governments” (Fox, 2009, p.277). In a society like Qatar where important segments of the population take religious legitimacy seriously, religious actors can extend or Page | 103 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 withhold their legitimacy from certain actions. Thus Qatari leaders, like other Islamic rulers leaders, refer religious text and invoke Qatar’s Arab heritage— rather than citing state constitutions—as a basis for its policies. Although governments may have significant influence on religious authorities and legitimacy is not the only concern for the state rulers, rulers may refrain from pursuing religiously unpopular foreign policies if such policies are not intimately related to regime survival. For example, while Qatar allow Israel to establish a trade office in Qatar, it closed it down in parallel with the rise of anti-Israeli sentiments during the Israel’s assault to Gaza in 2008. Furthermore, religion shapes the perception of external actors. In the case of Qatar four layers of international audience—Arab, Muslim, and Western states, international community—play prominent role in Qatari foreign policy. For the first two of these layers, Islam an important factor in considering in judging Qatar’s foreign policy. Qatari state rulers often take Arab and Muslim criticism seriously and attempt to persuade these audiences for the legitimacy of their foreign policies. One case for this is Qatar’s relations with Israel. In part to build closer relations with the US, just after ousting his father, the new Emir attempted to normalize relations with Israel. Despite the public opinion against the normalization, Israeli Prime Minister Shimon Peres visited Qatar and Israel opened a trade office in Doha in 1996. When criticized that this normalization undermines Arab and Muslim interest, Qatar argued its sovereign right to conduct foreign policy autonomously (Rabi, 2009, p.449). Yet Qatari Government also took actions such as establishing committee to support Arab and Islamic heritage of Jerusalem to show its commitment to pan-Arab and “Islamic” cause (Rabi, 2009, p.450). Each wave of Arab-Israeli, Arab and Islamic circles ratcheted up their criticism about the existence of Israel’s trade office in Doha. Second (Al-Aqsa) Intifada resulted in more internal and regional calls for Qatari government end ties with Israel. Qatari desire in hosting the Organization of Islamic Conference/Cooperation (OIC) summit in Doha in November 2000 made it more vulnerable to the criticism about its relations with Israel (Rabi, 2009, p.451). Established a reaction to Israel’s expansion in 1967 and control of Jerusalem, one of the primary objections of the OIC is to deny international legitimacy in to the Israeli occupation beyond its 1967 boundaries. Arab and Muslim actors argued that Doha’s relations with Israel made it unsuitable to host the OIC meeting and thus a serious actor in the region and broader Muslim world (Kayaoglu, 2015). “Eventually, Qatar succumbed to regional pressure, and announced the closure of the Israeli office in November 2000. A government spokesman stated that the Page | 104 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 closure ‘reinforces Arab solidarity and creates appropriate conditions for holding the summit.’” (Rabi, 2009, p.452). 3.3. Third Cut: Religion as a Way of Life and Public Islam on Qatar’s Foreign Policy Unlike political scientist, many anthropologists and sociologists have abandoned the “social-scientific” view of religion in general and Islam in particular. For example, the anthropologist Talal Asad cautions against thinking of Islam as merely a belief calling it privatized, which is the Protestant view of religion that reduces religion to inner convictions (forum internum). He likewise questions thinking about religion as culture or identity. He suggests thinking of religion not as a state of mind or blue print of society, but as a form of activity and practice in the world (Asad, 1993).Rejecting the construction of religion as a category that can be studied, he asks us to view religion as a “discursive tradition” in which doctrine and practices mutually inform each other, making contextdependent shared understanding of Islam that in turn shape Muslims’ everyday life. Shared habits and practices grounded in Islam have contributed to the formation of conceptions of Islamically legitimated social action in public life what Eickelman and Salvatore call “public Islam” (Eickelman & Salvatore, 2002, p.101). This approach moves beyond formal authority a structure that is discussed in the previous section. In other words, the influence and power of Islam lies not only with its place in formal authority structures, but more so with its ability to shape “accepted and socially legitimated means of accomplishing a task.” Islam thus provides “background clusters of concepts, shared understandings, and practices” that underpin the public sphere (Eickelman & Salvatore, 2002, p.99). Eickelman and Saltvatore argue that mass education and media throughout the Muslim-majority world have contributed to the re-emergence of a robust public sphere. In this public sphere, there is a wide spectrum of people engaging political and religious debates in which they invoke Islam to discuss Islamically legitimated practices. These public debates about Islam reconfigure the politics and social life in Muslim societies by changing political ideas and also religious habits, practices, and discourses. Thus, these debates mold in the participants a new identity and new forms of social relations. As growing numbers of people participate in the public sphere, these activities challenge authoritarian structures, lead to the fragmentation of political and religious authority, and expand debates on issues of common good (al-maslaha al-‘amma) (Eickelman & Salvatore, 2002, p.98). Page | 105 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 Unlike political Islam, public Islam focuses on how religion shapes and can be shaped in everyday practices and questions. Islam requires its followers to carry out a myriad of activities regularly such as to pray five times a day, follow dietary rules (halal), fast during the month of Ramadan, wear modest clothes (hijab), go to pilgrimage (hajj), and avoid usury (riba), spread Islam (dawa), and giving tithe (zakat). Seeing this way, Islam is a deen, righteous path that Muslims should follow to comply with the Sharia, Islamic law that shapes significant aspects of everyday practice of Muslims. Islam’s influence in Qatar’s public sphere is all-pervasive. Islam as set of values, norms, and principles that informs and guides the life of the society of believers—has long become as reference with which the society identifies itself. These norms, values, and principles are continuously practiced in Qatar’s public sphere (except for some extraterritorial enclaves), such as the ban of alcohol, gender segregation, and dress code. For these everyday practices, values, norms, and principles, Muslims offer public reasoning based on religious teachings by citing not only Quran or hadith but also religious scholars’ interpretations they learn through popular media, books, Friday sermons (usually well-attended), or other religious gatherings. These platforms allow religious scholars to construct a public theology that deals not only issues about religious faith and practices but also social, economic, and political implications religious faith and practice. In other words, even when religious scholars are excluded from the formal political decision-making processes, they continue to have enormous influence on shaping social values and frame of references of society and thus influence politics indirectly (through popular legitimacy and mobilization) or directly by shaping decision-makers’ values and frame references. The growth of public Islam is visible in Qatar. Qatar has a comparatively open public sphere among Arab states for the discussion of politics and religion. The Qatari population is increasingly well-educated, and internet penetration in Qatari society is very high. “The Global Mufti” Yusuf al-Qaradawi and the media giant Al Jazeera bolsters a public sphere in which public Islam took increasingly stronger roots (Gräf & Skovgaard-Petersen, 2009). In contrast to the perspectives of political Islam that downplay the role of Islam in Qatari politics, public Islam predicts this strong public sphere will have significant influence on Qatari politics. Few would dispute that the coverage of Al-Jazeera or Al-Qaradawi’s frequent sermons in Qatari Mosques has influence over Arab and Muslim politics. While Qatari elite has some control over these mediums that have increasingly shaped the Arab public sphere, the elite’s views are also shaped these coverage and sermons. For example, while some survival instinct or prestige can be related to Page | 106 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 Qatari mediation into conflicts, it is inconceivable that Qatari leadership would consider to intervene or mediate an issue that is not extensively covered by Al Jazeera. This does not mean that Qatar will involve on issues extensively covered by Al Jazeera, but it means that Al Jazeera coverage might also informs Qatari leadership about these issues and shapes their understanding of Qatari interest about these. Similarly, powerful voices such as Qaradawi is not in position to get Qatar act on a specific issue, but he can inform and shape Qatari view of Islamic values and politics as well as Muslim practices. For example he publicly and strongly holds a strong pro-Palestinian position and argues that Muslims should support Hamas and Hezballah as legitimate resistance movement against Israel, “based on Quranic injunctions to defend Muslim territory invaded by outsiders” (Blanchard, 2010). Qatar is a great case for the identification of the mechanisms through which public Islam can influence foreign policy because strategic factors limit the influence of religion, domestic structures marginalize factors related to political Islam, and yet there is a healthy public sphere in which public Islam exists. From the perspective of thinking Islam as a way of life and examining its influence on Qatar’s foreign policy, with its public sphere and the centrality of Islam in Qatar’s society should be integral to any explanation of Qatar’s foreign policy. Yet the research on religion and foreign policy so far has not identified how exactly the debates on religious practices public sphere influences foreign policies. Under what conditions and what kind of public spheres may be more conducive to religious influences on foreign policies? Similarly, scholarship on Qatar has not explored the role of public Islam and everyday practices of Islam on Qatar’s foreign policy. How do debates about and practices of zakat influence Qatar’s foreign aid? How do debates about Jerusalem in Qatar’s public sphere influence foreign policies towards Israel? These are the type of questions the third cut— Islam as a way of life—would ask scholar to pay attention. 4. Conclusion This paper has three conclusions. First, the instrumentalist approaches that emphasize Qatari foreign policy through strategic decisions that reduces Qatar’s foreign policy obsessively focusing on its survivability or its brand are incomplete and fails to offer a comprehensive account Qatar’s foreign policy activism. Moreover these approaches neglect the role of Islam plays in Qatari foreign policy. This neglect may be understandable because Qatari domestic political system does not allow political Islamist actors to influence Qatari politics. Page | 107 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 Second, the tendency among scholars to reduce the role of Islam to political Islam and to what “Islamic” actors do not make justice to complex ways that Islam influences foreign policy. This influence is mostly constitutive—rather than causal—in informing and shaping foreign policy elites about the nature of problem and their own interest. By doing so, this religious influence dispose— rather than cause, in a narrow sense of the word—to deal with particular issues, to understand their preferences in certain ways, and develop some policies not others. Third, there are three ways in which religious factors can influence foreign policies of states that cannot be captured by a narrow understanding of politics and causality. First way sees religion as belief: political actors have particular religious beliefs that lead them to certain political and foreign policy choices. Second way sees religion as identity and a source of legitimacy: political actors often need to consider what domestic and international audience would consider legitimate. Third way sees religion as a way of life which shapes and is shaped in debates in public sphere and religious practices: debates in public sphere about Islam—such as to whom zakat can be given—may influence a Qatar’s foreign aid policies as at least some portion of Qatar’s foreign aid budget is considered zakat. References A bouncy bantam: A Gulf state asserts itself in the world (2006, September 7). The Economist. Asad, T. (1993). Genealogies of Religion: Discipline and Reasons of Power in Christianity and Islam. Baltimore, MD: The John Hopkins University Press. Ayoob, M. ( 2011). American Policy Toward the Persian Gulf. In M. Kamrava (Ed.), International Politics of the Persian Gulf, (pp.120-143). New York: Syracuse University Press. Barakat, S. (2012). The Qatari Spring: Qatar’s Emerging Role in Peacemaking. Retrieved from www.lse.ac.uk/government/research/resgroups/kuwait/documents/TheQatari-Spring%20-%20Qatars-Emerging-Role-in-Peacemaking.pdf Baskan, B., and Wright, S. (2010). Seeds of Change: Comparing State-Religion Relations in Qatar and Saudi Arabia. Arab Studies Quarterly, 33 (2), 96111. Blanchard, C.M. (2010). Qatar: Background and U.S. Relations. Congressional Research Service. Retrieved from www.fas.org/sgp/crs/mideast/RL31718.pdf Page | 108 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 Cooper, A.F., and Momani, B. (2009). The Challenge of Re-branding Progressive Countries in the Gulf and Middle East. Place Branding and Public Diplomacy, 5 (2), 103-117. Constitution of Qatar. (2004). Retrieved from portal.www.gov.qa/wps/portal/about-qatar Eakin, H. (2011). The Strange Power of Qatar. The New York Review of Books. Eickelman, D.F., and Salvatore, A. (2002). The Public Sphere and Muslim Identities. Archieve European Sociology, XLIII, 92-115. Foley, S. (2010). Kuwait, Qatar, the UAE, Bahrain, and Oman. In B. Rubin (Ed.), Guide to Islamist Movements (pp. 305-318). Fox, J. (2009). Integrating Religion into IR Theory. In J. Haynes (Ed.), Routledge Handbook of Religion and Politics (pp. 273-292). Fromherz, A.J. (2012). Qatar: Washington Press. A Modern History. Washington D.C.: George Gräf, B., and Skovgaard-Petersen, J. (2009). Global Mufti: The Phenomenon of Yusuf al-Qaradawi. New York: Columbia University Press. Gunn, T.J. (2003). The Complexity of Religion and the Definition of Religion in International Law. Harvard Human Rights Journal, 16, 189-215. Henne, P. (2011). Modified Selectorate Theory and Domestic Religious Influences on International Relations: A Case of Turkey’s Foreign Policy. Conference paper presented at International Studies Association Annual Meeting, Montreal, Canada. Hopf, T. (2010). The Logic of Habit in International Relations. European Journal of International Relations, 16 (4), 539-561. Human Rights Watch. (2012). Human Rights in Qatar. Retrieved from www.hrw.org/middle-eastn-africa/qatar Hurd, I. (1999). Legitimacy and Authority in International Politics. International Organizations, 53 (2), 379-408. Kamrava, M. (2009). Royal Factionalism and Political Liberalization in Qatar. Middle East Journal, 63 (3), 401-420. Kamrava, M. (2011a). International Politics of the Persian Gulf. New York: Syracuse University Press. Page | 109 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 Kamrava, M. (2011b). Mediation and Qatari Foreign Policy. Middle East Journal, 64 (4), 539-556. Kayaoglu, T. (2015). The Organization of Islamic Cooperation: Politics, Problems, and Potential. London: Routledge. Kostiner, J. (2011). GCC Perceptions of Collective Security in the Post-Saddam Era, In M. Kamrava (Ed.), International Relations of the Persian Gulf (pp. 94119). Lambert, J. (2011). Political Reform in Qatar: Participation, Legitimacy, and Security. Middle East Policy, XVIII (1), 89-101. Lawson, F.H. (2011). Security Dilemmas in the Contemporary Gulf. In M. Kamrava (Ed.), International Relations of the Persian Gulf (pp. 50-71). Peterson, J.E. (2006). Qatar and the World: Branding for a Micro-State. Middle East Journal, 60 (4), 732-748. Pgymy with the punch of a giant (2011, November 5). The Economist Pouliot, V. (2008). The Logic of Practicality: A Theory of Practice of Security Communities. International Organization, 62 (2), 257-288. Priess, D. (1996). Balance of Threat Theory and the Genesis of the Gulf Cooperation Council. Security Studies, 5 (4), 143-71. Roberts, D.B. (2009). Qatar’s Search for Security. Proceedings of the Plymouth Postgraduate Symposium, 245-255. Rosman-Stollman, E. (2009). Qatar: Liberalization as Foreign Policy. In J. Teitelbaum (Ed.), Political liberalization in the Persian Gulf (pp. 287-209). New York: Columbia University Press. Rabi, U. (2009). Qatar’s Relations with Israel: Challenging Arab and Gulf Norms. The Middle East Journal, 63 (3),443-459. Shadid, A. (2011, November 14). Qatar Wields An Outsize Influence in Arab Politics. The New York Times. Shaffer, B. (Ed.) (2006). The Limits of Culture: Islam and Foreign Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Shushan, D. (2011). Bold Moves for a Small State: An Analysis of Qatar’s Foreign Policy. Paper presented at International Studies Association Annual Conference, Montreal, Canada. Page | 110 T. Kayaoğlu / EJEPS 8 (2015) 93-111 State Department. (2011). 2010 Human Rights Report: Qatar. Retrieved from http://www.state.gov/documents/organization/160077.pdf Telhami, S., and Barnett, M. (Ed.). (2002). Identity and Foreign Policy in the Middle East. Ithaca: Cornel University Press. Wendt, A. (1999). Social Theory of International Politics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wright, S. (2011). Qatar. In C. Davidson (Ed.), Power and Politics in the Persian Gulf Monarchies (pp. 113-134). New York: Columbia University Press. Wright, S. (2011b). Foreign Policy in the GCC States. In M. Kamrava (Ed.), International Politics of the Persian Gulf (pp. 72-91). Syracuse: Syracuse University Press. Wright, S. (2012). Foreign Policies with International Reach: The Case of Qatar. In D. Held & K. Ulrichsen (Eds.), Transformation of Gulf: Politics, Economics, and the Global Order (pp. 296-312). Page | 111 Page | 112 EUROPEAN JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL STUDIES GUIDE FOR AUTHORS Procedures for reviewing manuscripts are based on the anonymity of the author and the confidentiality of readers’ and editors’ reports. As author anonymity is preserved during the editorial decision-making process, self-references should be removed. Referees are drawn from Fatih and other institutions; published articles have usually been reviewed by the editors and at least two peer-reviewers. EJEPS does not accept manuscripts that have already been published, are scheduled for publication elsewhere, or have been simultaneously submitted to another journal. Statements of fact and opinion appearing in the journal are made on the responsibility of the authors alone and do not imply the endorsement of the editors or publisher. The editors strive to complete the review process within two months. ARTICLE SUBMISSION GUIDELINES Papers should be in English. Submit manuscripts electronically to [email protected] in Microsoft Word format (No Submission Fee). Papers that are submitted to EJEPS for publication should not be under review at other journals. The first page of the manuscript should contain: The title The name(s) and institutional affiliation(s) of the author(s) The address, telephone, and fax numbers (as well as the email address) of the corresponding author and co-authors. An abstract of 250 words 6 keywords JEL categories Page Setup: The structure of paper (W:17cm x H:24cm) should follow margins: 2.5 cm from top and bottom, and 2 cm right and left. Text: A single space should be used in text, with 6 pt space after each paragraph. The font in main body should be Calibri font in 11 pt. type. Additionally, equations should be in Microsoft Word-Equation form. Figures and tables should be numbered consecutively in Arabic numerals. Use dot for a decimal separator, and comma for a thousands-separator. Consider only 4 digits after decimal point (Ex: 62.88%). Tables & Figures should be manually prepared (editable, not in picture formats). Page | 113 Manuscripts should be approximately 5,000 to 8,000 words. Longer manuscripts will be considered only in exceptional circumstances. Manuscripts should be original works and must not be submitted elsewhere while under consideration by EJEPS. Articles will be reviewed by the Editors and will be forwarded for peer review upon their assessment. The citations should follow APA 6th referencing system, and references should be listed at the end of the main text in alphabetical order. The text font for footnotes should be Calibri, and size should be 10 pt type. They should be kept to a minimum, and lengthy notes are strongly discouraged. GENERAL AGREEMENT EJEPS will own copyright to all published works and have the right of first publication, both in print and online, unless other arrangements are made with the Editors in advance. REVIEW PROCESS European Journal of Economic and Political Studies (EJEPS) employs two-stage review process. At first step, (one of) the editor(s) of the journal will review the article in order to decide if it is worthy of peer-review. If the article can pass this first review, it will then be sent to two anonymous peer-reviewers (double-blind review). Within 4 to 8 weeks, the authors will receive an email from the journal announcing the decision which will be accompanied by the reviewers' comments. APA 6th EDITION CITATION (REFERENCING) The following examples illustrate citations using the APA 6th edition citation system. Each example of a reference list entry is accompanied by an example of a corresponding parenthetical citation in the text. Followings are few examples. Book Pollan, M. (2006). The Omnivore’s Dilemma: A Natural History of Four Meals. New York: Penguin. Journal Article Weinstein, J.I. (2009). The Market in Plato’s Republic. Classical Philology, 104 (2), 439–58. (Pollan, 2006, pp.99–100) (Weinstein, 2009, p.440) Page | 114 Page | 115 Page | 116