An Analysis and Proposal for Insider Trading Regulation
Transcription
An Analysis and Proposal for Insider Trading Regulation
University of Pennsylvania Law School Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship 1991 Start Making Sense: An Analysis and Proposal for Insider Trading Regulation Jill E. Fisch University of Pennsylvania Law School, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, Business Organizations Law Commons, Civil Procedure Commons, Criminal Law Commons, Economic Policy Commons, Economics Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Legal Studies Commons, Litigation Commons, and the Securities Law Commons Recommended Citation Fisch, Jill E., "Start Making Sense: An Analysis and Proposal for Insider Trading Regulation" (1991). Faculty Scholarship. Paper 1036. http://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/1036 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. START MAKING SENSE: AN ANALYSIS AND PROPOSAL FOR INSIDER TRADING REGULATION* Jill E. Fisch** When C harles Dickens wrote " the law is a[n] ass ,"1 he might well have been describing the law governing insider trading.2 The history of government enforcement in this area, including the re cent litigation over broker Robert Chestman 's trading in Waldbaum stock,3 demonstrates that the legal restrictions on trad ing securities while in p ossession of material non public information are confused and confusing. 4 The legal uncertainty has been attrib- * Copyright b y J ill E. F i s c h , 1 99 1 . T h e title refers t o the TALKING HEADS film SToP MAKING SENSE ( Columbia Pictures 1 984) and the album of the same name. * * Associate Professor, Fordham U n iversity School of Law; B.A. 1982, Cornell U niversity; J . D . 1 985, Yale Law School. I a m grateful to Victor Brudney, Roberta Karmel, Donald Langevoort, Roberta Romano, and Steve The! for reading and commenting on earlier drafts of this Article and to Gary Leibowitz for his research assistance. ' CHARLES DICKENS, OLIVER TWIST 335 ( Oxford Univ. P ress 1 966) ( 1 838) . 2 The term i ns ider trading is generally used to describe trading in securities on the basis of material nonpublic information about the securities themselves, the issuer of the securi ties, or the market for the securities. In its broadest sense, insider trading can be conducted by those who are not typically considered corporate insiders and may include trading that does not violate existing law as well as conduct that has been held to be unlawfu l . Cf. DoN· ALD C. LANGEVOORT, I NSIDER TRADING REGULATION 5 ( 1 991 ) (definin g insider trading as "un· lawful trading i n securities by p e rsons who possess material nonpublic i n formation about the company whose shares are traded or the market for its shares"). 3 See United States v. C hestman, 903 F.2d 7 5 (2d Cir. 1 990), vaca ted in part on reh 'g , 947 F.2d 551 (2d Cir. 1 9 9 1 ) ( en bane) . After the Second Circuit overturned his criminal conviction, Chestman attempted to modify his civil settlement with the Securities and Ex change Commission (SEC) on the basis that the decision i n the criminal case cast doubt on the legal basis for the civil action. The court refused to overturn the settlement agreement. SEC v. C hestman, 87 C iv. 7 1 48 (RJW) ( S . D . N.Y. 1 99 1 ) ; see Court Rejec ts Efforts by Ex· St ockbroker to Block Paymen t from Sett lement Fun d , 23 Sec. Reg. & L . Rep. (BNA) No. 10, at 369 ( Mar. 8, 1 99 1 ) . ' See, e.g . , SEC- CFTC Compromise to Receive Priority When Congress Convenes i n '91, Dobb Says, 22 Sec. Reg. & L. Rep. (BNA) No. 45, at 1 59 1 -98 ( Nov. 1 6 , 1 990) ( reporting suggestion by panelists at Nov. 9, 1990 Annual Meeting of ABA Business Law Section on Federal Regulation of Securities Commission that Chestman decision could revive interest in a legislative definition of insider trading) . 1 79 1 80 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 26:1 79 uted to the absence of a statute defining the prohibited conduct.5 Because the government has devoted increased time and resources to the battle against insider trading and has taken an aggressive l itigation posture whereby it seeks to draw an ever-greater scope of activity into the web of prohibited conduct,6 the ambiguity of the regulations is particularly troubling. • Many commentators have publicly expressed concern over the absence of clear statutory guidelines. See, e.g. , James D. Cox, Choices: Paving the Road Toward a "Defin i t i o n" of Insider Trading, 39 ALA. L. REv. 3 8 1 , 381 ( 1 988) ( " [Ijt is i m perative that Congress define insider trading."); Donald C. Langevoort, S e t t i ng the Agenda f o r Legislative Reform: S o m e Fallacies, Anomalies, a n d Other Curiosities i n t h e Prevailing L a w o f Insider Trading, 39 ALA. L. REv. 399, 409 - 1 3 (1 988) (calling for r e form of insider trading regulatio n ) ; Richard M . P h i ll i ps & Larry R. Lavoie, The SEC's Proposed Insider Trading L egis la t ion: Insider Trad- . ing Controls, Corpora te Secrecy, a n d Full Disclosure, 39 ALA. L. R E v 439, 440 ( 1988) ( " [T]he case-by-case approach has failed to produce a rational, comprehensible definition that the average person can apply with predictability."); Richard M . P hillips & Robert ,J. Zutz, The Insider Trading Doctrine: A Need for Legislative Repair, 1 3 HoFSTRA L. REv. 65, 7 1 ( 1984) (citing need for legislation to "strip insider trading restrictions from the rubric of fraud") ; Iman Anabtawi, Note, Toward a Definition of Insider Trading, 41 STAN. L. REv. 377, 385 ( 1989) (arguing existing prohibition i s inconsistent and fails to consider i mpact on market efficiency of i nsider trad i n g ) ; see a lso Elkan A bramowitz, Defin e or A bs ta i n: The Congressiona l Gap in Insider Trading, 204 N.Y L.J. 3, 3 ( 1 990) ( " [l ] ndividuals are subject to severe criminal sanctions for a crime that has never been defined or expressly p rohibited by federal statute . . . . " ) ; Roberta S . Karmel, Defining Insider Trading, 198 N.Y L.J. 1, 34 ( 1 987) (stating that fai lure to define conduct which is subject of criminal sanctions violates due p rocess) ; Otto G. Obermaier, Who 's an Insider? Wha t 's Inside<, 196 N.Y L.J. 1, 2 ( 1986) (stating that "convoluted legal theorizing" about insider trading is necessary because of a b sence of statutory definition ) ; H arvy L . P itt & K a r l A . Groskaufmanis, Family Ties, Tip pees a n d the Chestman Decision: Time for a Principled Definition of Insider Trading, IN SIGHTS, July 1 990, at 7 ( c iting "pressing need" for statutory definition of insider trading); Moncito Williams, What 's Lega l-a n d What's Not , FoRTUNE, Dec. 22, 1 986, at 36 ( noting that i nsider trading rules are " amazingly vague"); SEC u. ?, WALL ST. J, Nov. 20, 1 986, at 34 ( bl aming SEC for lack of clear d e fi n ition for insider trading) . When Congress promulgated the Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1 984 it considered i n cluding a definition of insider trading b u t decided not t o do s o , believing that t h e existing substantive law was adequately clear. Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1983: Hearings o n H.R. 559 Before the Subcomm. o n Securities o f the Sen a t e Comm. o n Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, 98th Cong., 2d Sess. 33-39 ( 1984 ) ; Definition of Insider Trading (Part !): Hearings Before the Subcomm. o n Securities of the Sen a t e Comm. on Ba nking, Housing a n d Urban Affa irs, 1 00th Cong. , 1 st Sess. 3 ( 1987) (statement of Sen. D'Amato) ( calling it " absolutely unrealistic to go by the standard which says, 'Well, I know it when I see it but I can't tell you what it is. I can't define it.' " ) ; cj. 1 3 3 Co N G. REc. S8246 (daily e d . June 1 7 , 1987) (statement o f Sen. Riegle) ( " [ U]ncertainties in t h e law a r e bad for both the govern ment and law abiding market participants . . . . [U ] n certainty about what conduct is or is not i l l egal creates confusion, causes needless anxiety for persons who desire to obey the law . . . and promotes d isrespect for the law. " ) . 6 See infra notes 90- 1 1 3 a n d accompanying text for examples of t h i s expanded prohi bition. I j1 l l INSIDER TRADING 1 99 1 ] 181 The lack o f clear guidelines can b e attributed, at least i n part, to the legislative policy of keeping the scope of prohibited conduct as broad as possible.' The consequence, however, is that traders are receiving prison sentences8 for conduct that, at the time of prose cution, presents j udicial issues of first impression.9 The imposition of prison terms in such cases implicates obvious due process con cerns.1 0 7 By defining insider trading, some legislators fear they will be creating a " roadmap for fraud" by providing guidance to traders as to activities that do not fall within the statutory prohibition. See, e.g. , Stuart J . K aswell, An Insider's View of the Insider Trading and Se curities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988, 45 Bus. LAw. 1 45 , 1 50 ( 1 989) ( detailing opposition of Chairman Dingell of Subcommittee on Oversight and I nvestigations of H ouse Committee on Energy and Commerce to enacting statutory definition) . Although the government's con cern that a definition will constrain enforcement attempts is valid, the alternative is expan sion of the criminal law through a form of judicial legislation, a process that is contrary to traditional con...ti tutional and historical limitations on the development of criminal law. See John C . Coffee, Jr., The 'Tip ' of the Bunny 's Nose: Sniffing Out Crime Where None Exists, LEGAL TIMES, Sept. 25, 1 989, at 34, 35 ( noting that law of insider trading is developing through after-the-fact judicial decision making and that this practice violates separation-of powers doctrine). The SEC has continually opposed the enactment of a statutory defi n ition. S e e HR REP. No. 355, 98th Cong., 1 s t Sess. 1 4, reprinted in 1 984 U . S . C . C.A.N. 2274, 2 287 ( relying on SEC recommendation that "any effort to define insider trading would result in . . . a rule that leaves gaping holes" ) . The General Accounting Office, however , recommended that Congress enact a statutory definition. UNITED STATES GENERAL AccouNTING O F FICE. REPORT TO THE C H AIRMAN, SuscoMM. ON OvERSIGHT AND INVESTIGATIONS C oMM. oN ENERGY AND CoM MERCE. HOUSE O F REPRESENTATIVES: SECU RITIES REGULATION, EFFORTS TO DETECT, INVESTI GATE. AND DETER INSIDER TRADING 3, 6 1 -63 ( 1988 ) . 8 Robert Chestman was sentenced to t w o years in j a i l , s o m e of which had b e e n served by the time his conviction for insider trading was reversed by the Second Circuit panel. United States v. Chestma n , 903 F.2d 7 5 (2d Cir. 1990 ) , vacated in part on reh 'g, 947 F . 2d 551 (2d Cir. 1 99 1 ) (en bane ) ; Martin Flumenbaum & B rad S. Karp, Second Circuit Review, 203 NY L.J. 3 , 5 ( 1990 ) . R . Foster Winans was sentenced to an 1 8 - m onth term i n prison. Un ited States v. Carpenter, 791 F.2d 1 024 (2d Cir. 1 986) , aff'd by a n equally divided Court, 484 U.S. 1 9 , 24 ( 1987 ) ; M artin Kimel, Note, The Inadequacy of Rule JOb-5 to A d dress Ou tsider Trading by Reporters, 38 STAN. L. R Ev 1 549, 1 54 9 n . 1 ( 1 986). Even in the 1 970s, before the emphasis on prison sentences for insider trading, Vincent Chiarella, a financial printer, \Vas sentenced to serve one month in prison. U nited States v. Chiarella, 588 F.2d 1 358, 1364 n.7 ( 2d Cir. 1978), rev 'd, 445 U . S . 2 2 2 ( 1 980) . 9 See Kaswell, supra note 7, at 1 5 1 ( describing Congressman Rinaldo's position in favor of enacting a definition) . According to Kaswell, Congressman Rinaldo believed it was " un reasonable for the securities industry and the public to be subject to severe penalties for a crime that some say can be und erstood only after a detailed textual exegesis of cour t deci sions and administrative proceedings. " Id. 10 The Ches t m a n case demonstrates the difficulties associated with the "fl exible" concept of insider tr::�ding espoused by the SEC. C hestman argued to the Second C ircuit that a criminal prosecution under the existing insider trading regulation violated his due process rights. See, e.g . Reply Brief for A ppellant at 24; United States v. C hestman, 90:3 F.2d 75 (2d . . 182 GEORGIA LA W RE VIE W [ V ol. 26: 1 7 9 The absence o f a clear definition o f the prohibited conduct may also hamper the efficient functioning of the capital markets. In an efficient market, all available information about a corporation and its securities will be incorporated into the stock price.u If, how ever, analysts and traders must investigate fully the source of all trading information in order to protect themselves from prosecu tion, they will be unable to trade rapidly on rumors, hearsay, and other common sources of information. 1 2 Similarly, if all market p articipants are subject to a duty to disclose or abstain based sim p ly on their possession of m aterial nonpublic information , they will be discouraged from attempting to seek out superior information because of their inability to profit from it. 1 3 The Supreme C ourt Cir. 1 990) ( No. 89- 1 276) ("It is thus fundamentally unfair to punish as a felon a stockbroker who could not possibly have been expected to understand and conform to esoteric theories construing undefi ned laws under ambiguous circumstances. " ) (on file with the Georgia Law Review). When Judge Jon 0. Newman inquired at the e n bane reargument of the C h es t man deci sion why the SEC had not promulgated a definition of insider trading, Paul Gonson, arguing on behalf of the SEC, responded that the SEC h a d been unable to do so because de.fi ning insider trading was "too daunting a tas k . " K ar l Groskaufmanis, The SEC's Enforcement Nose Dive, LEGA L TIMES, Dec. 1 6, 1 9 9 1 , at 2 1 . The obvious response to this argument, as observed by the court, is that i f the S EC cannot define insider trading, how can C h estman be expected to? At least one commentator has also argued that this form of jud icial legislation v iolates constitutional principles of separation o f powers. C offee , supra note 7, at 3 5 . " S e e , e.g. , B asic, Inc. v. Levinson, 4 8 5 U.S. 2 2 4 , 24 6 ( 1988) (" Recent e m p irical studies have tended to confirm Congress' premise that the market price of shares traded on wel l developed markets reflects all publicly available i n formation . . . . " ) . T h e e fficient market theory, or efficient capital market hypothesis, has achieved wide acceptance by the legal culture. !d. at 253 n.4 (White, J., d issenting i n part) ( quoting Ronald J . G i lson & Reinier H. Kraakman, The Mechanisms of Mark e t Efficiency, 70 VA. L REv. 549, 549-50 ( 19 84 ) ) . For a detailed d iscussion of efficient market theory and an analysis of whether the stock markets function e fficiently, see Lynn A. Stout, The Unimportance of Being Efficient: A n Economic A n a lysis of Stock Market Pricing a n d Securi ties Regu l a tion, 87 MICH. L. REv. 6 1 3 ( 1 988 ) . S e e also D aniel R . Fischel, Use of Modern Finance Theory i n Securities Frau d Cases In vo lving Actively Traded Securities, 38 Bus. LAw. 1, 4 n.9 ( 1 982) ( citing efficient m arket theory literature). 12 M any traders, notably risk arbitrageurs, make their profit by trad ing on information that is not wholly public, at least in the sense that such information is not yet fully reflected in stock prices. See Coffee, supra note 7 , at 34. 13 As Professor Brudney observes, " [e ] xploration for relevant corporate and economic i n formation is a service o f value i n t h e functioning of t h e market." Victor B ru d n ey, Insiders , Outsiders, and Informa tional Advantages Under the Federal Securities Laws, 93 H A RV. L. REv. 322, 3 4 1 ( 1 979) . This exploration is costly, however, and will not be undertaken unless the discoverer of the i n formation has the opportunity to capitalize on his d i scovery. The most direct way for the discoverer to capitalize on the informational advantage is by buying 1991 ] 1 83 INSIDER TRADING has expressly recognized that securities analysts perform an essen tial function in making the markets more efficient by disseminat ing market information and causing that information to be re flected in stock prices.14 This role cannot survive in a market in which trading is permitted only upon a parity of information. 15 The litigation history of insider trading reveals fundamental dis agreement over the rationale behind the prohibition as well as its s cope. The prohibition has been developed within the framework of federal securities fraud , and the resulting case law contains logi cal as well as interpretive flaws. Moreover, litigation under the the ories of liability developed by the courts illustrates the practical drawbacks to a judge-made crime. The existing doctrines fai l to give adequate notice of prohibited conduct and present issues of interpretation that are simply unacceptable in a criminal statute. Concern that prohibited conduct be properly delineated has in tensified with congressional authorization of increased penalties for insider trading, the devotion of greater resources to criminal in sider trading prosecutions, and the government's announced inten tion to seek prison sentences more frequently.16 This enforcement activity poses a grave threat to due process concerns in the absence or selling securities. !d. " D irks v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 658 (1983). " Thus, in Dirks, the Court noted, " I m posi n g a duty to d isclose or abstain solely because a person knowingly receives material , nonpublic i n formation from an insider and trades on it could have an inhi b i ting influence on the role of market analysts, which the SEC itself recognizes is necessary to the preservation of a heal t hy m arket." !d. at 658. 16 See The Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988, Pub. L . No. 1 00-704, 1 02 Stat. 4677 ( codified as amended a t 15 U . S . C . A. § 78 (West 1981 & Supp. 1991)) (" ITSFEA") ( increasing statutory penalties and remedies for insider trading); The Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984, Pub. L . No. 98-376, 98 Stat. 1264 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C.A. § 78 ( West 1981 & Supp. 1991)); Howard M . Friedman, The Insider Trading and Securities Fra u d Enforcement A c t of 1988, 68 N.C. L. REv. 465, 476-81 (1990) ( ex plaining how ITSFEA clarified and expanded penalties for insider trading). The House Committee that drafted the 1988 amendments to the Securi ties Exchange Act of 1 934, § l, 15 U S.C § 78 (1988), expressed a desire to see a greater i m position of p rison senten ces in insider trad ing prosecutions. The Committee's interest i n the rr.aximum jail term i s a n explicit congressional statement of the heightened seriousness with which insider trading and other securities fraud offenses should be viewed. Alth ough the legislation does not include an explicit mandatory minimum sentence the Committee believes in the strongest possi ble manner that courts should i mpose jail terms for the com m ission of these crimes, and expects that raisi ng the ceiling will i ncrease the certainty of substantial prison sentences. HR HEr. i·-Jo. 910, 100th C ong., 2d Sess. 23, reprinted in 1988 U.S.C.C.A.N. 6 0 4 3 6060. , 1 84 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 of clear standards for traders as t o the legality of their conduct. Finally, because the United States was one of the first countries to develop extensive insider trading regulations and enforcement mechanisms , its experience has served as a model for much re cently enacted regulation by foreign sovereigns 1 7 and is receiving increased attention from the E uropean Economic Community ( EE C) in connection with its harmonization of European securities regulations. 1 8 This Article will demonstrate that the doctrine under which in sider trading is regulated is seriously flawed. Many of the flaws can be attributed to the fact that insider trading regulation has been developed on an ad hoc basis, with insufficient thought given to its rationale. The Article will review this development and examine, in particular , the judicial determination that insider trading is decep tive and thereby fraudulent because of the insider's breach of a fiduciary duty. After identifying the problems with this approach, the Article will turn to the question of whether i nsider trading should be illegal and, if so, why. C oncluding that regulation can be j ustified by both political and market forces, the Article will pro pose a revised regulatory scheme that clarifies the application of the prohibition while removing the twisted logical basis upon which the existing regulation is founded. I. OvERVIEW OF INSIDER TRADING Many of the difficulties with existing insider trading law result from its uneasy legal source. The federal securities laws do not " See LANGEVOORT, supra note 2, at 483-521 ( describing development a n d status ot in sider trading regulation i n various foreign j urisdiction s ) . insider trading (or insider dealing, as it is commonly referred to abroad) is also receiving increased attention overseas due to the proliferation of recent insider trading scandals outside the U n i ted States. Notable a mong these were the Tateho C hemical I ndustries Co. scandai and the Recruit Cosmos Co. scanda l in Japan and the Pechiney affair in France. For a description of the Tateho Chemi cal scandal, see Tomoko Akashi, Note, Regu l a t ion of Insider Trading in Japan, 89 CoLLr�o.t L. REv. 1296, 1302-03 (1989). For a description of the Recrui t Cosmos scanda l , see David W i l l iams, A Primer for Japan's L a t es t Political Scandal, LA TIMES, Apr. 16, 1989, pt. 5, at 2. For details on the Pechiney affair, see H . R. REP. No. 240, 101st Cong. , lst Sess. 6-7 (1989); LANCEVOORT, supra note 2, at 499-500. '" The European Economic Community has recently adopted an Insider Deal ing Direc tive, which sets forth m i n i mum regulatory standards for member states. The final version of the Ins ider Dealing D irective is printed at 1989 O.J. (L 334) 30. A detailed analyo:.is of the Insider Dealing D i rective can be found in K laus J. Hopt, Th e Europea n Insider Dealing Dlrectice, '27 co�.!M. MKT. L. REV. 5 1 (1990). 1 99 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 1 85 contain an express prohibition of insider trading . 1 9 Instead, the co nclusion that insider trading is i llegal has evolved from SEC and judicial interpretation of the general antifraud provisions of the federal securities laws , section 1 0 (b) of the Securities Exchange A ct20 (the Exchange Act) and SEC Rule 1 0b-5 thereunder.2 1 19 The only sections of the Securities Exchange Act of 1 934 that directly address trading by insiders are section 1 6, 1 5 U . S . C . § 78p ( 1988) (sometimes referred to as the "other i n sider trading statute," see, e.g. , DoNALD C . LANGEVOORT, INSIDER TRADING REGULATION c h . 1 0 ( 1 9 9 1 ) ( d escribing section 1 6 a s a " secondary tool" i n fight against insider trading)) and section 20A, 1 5 U.S.C. § 78t- 1 ( 1 988) ( added by the 1 988 amendments to the Exchange Act) . Broadly speaking, section 1 6 ( b ) provides that profits earned by statutory insiders-defined as officers, d irectors, and 10% stockholders-through short-term trading in their company's stock belong to the corporation. Section 1 6 ( a ) requires the reporting of all i nsider trades to the SEC on a monthly basis, and section 1 6 ( c ) prohibits certain insider trading outright, including short sales and selling against the box. Section 16(b) describ es as its purpose the prevention of "the unfair use of i nformation which may have been obtained by [an insider] by reason of his relationship to the issuer." Liability under section 1 6 does not require the misuse of inside i n formation; the provision i mposes strict liability on the basis of short-term trading. 1 5 U.S.C. § 78p ( 1 988) . Nor does its coverage extend to trad ing on the basis of i nside information, if that trading does not take place within the statutory six-month pe riod. !d. Because of these l imitations, commentators frequently have described section 1 6 as a "blunt tool" for the regulation of i nsider trading and have expressed d issatisfaction with it. See, e.g. , Steve The!, The Genius of Section 16: Regu l a ting the Managem e n t of Publicly Held Companies, 42 HASTINGS L.J. 391 , 396 n n . 9 & 1 0 ( 1 99 1) (citing descriptions of section 16 as "crude" and "arbitrary"). When the Exchange Act was passed, however, Congress felt that identifying and prosecuting insider trading d irectly was too d ifficult. Although it recog n ized that section 16 was not an a irtight provision against insider trading, Congress believed the Exchange Act would encourage voluntary abstention from i nsider trading. Because i t is difficult to draw a clear line as a matter of law between truly i nside information and i n formation generally known by the better-informed in vestors, the most potent weapon against the abuse of inside information is full and prompt publicity . . . . The Committee i s aware that these requirements are not air-tight and that the u nscrupulous i nsider may sti l l , within the law, use inside i nformation for his own advantage . . . . H.R REP. No. 1 383, 73d Cong. , 2d Sess. 1 3 ( 1 934 ) . B u t see The!, supra (argu ing that section 16 is not aimed at regulation of i nsider trading but rather focuses on preventing manage ment manipulation of corporate events to create trading opportunities) . Section 20A, although addressing i nsider trading, does not contain any direct lim itation on trading; it simply provides a private cause of action for persons who trade contemporane ously i n the market with inside traders. The section does not make insider trading illegal. I nstead, it bootstraps private civil liability onto other statutory or regulatory provisions. See 1 5 U. S.C. § 78t- l ( 1 988) . See generally William K . S . Wang, The "Cont empnraneous"' Tra d ers Who Can Sue a n Inside Trader, 38 H ASTINGS L.J. 1 1 75 ( 1 987) (discussing development of case law regard ing private actions by contemporaneous traders). '0 Section 10(b) provides: It shall be unlawful for any person, directly or indi rectly, by the use of any means or instrumentality of interstate commerce or of the mails, or of any facil ity of any national securities exchange- I 1 l 1 86 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 Neither section 1 0 (b ) n o r Rule 1 0 b - 5 explicitly refers t o insider trading. Instead, the SEC and the courts have concluded22 that the language prohibiting deception and fraud bars insider trading. Based on the reasoning accepted by the S upreme Court, insider trading is a fraudulent omission and therefore securities fraud . 23 Under the common-law tort of fraudulent misrepresentation, upon which much of the C ourt's interpretation of Rule 1 0b - 5 is based , liability may be premised on omissions-the failure to speak-as well as affirmative misstatements.24 An omission i s de ceptive or fraudulent under Rule 1 0b - 5 , however, only under c ir cumstances in which the defendant has a duty to speak . 2 5 S omeone who trades on the basis of inside information has not dece ived an- ( b ) t o use or employ, i n connection with the purchase o r sale of any security registered on a national securities exchange or any security not so registered , any manipulative or deceptive device or contrivance in contravention of such rules and regulations as the Commission may prescribe as necessary or a p pro priate i n the public interest or for the protection of i nvestors. 15 U.S.C. § 78j ( b ) ( 1988) . "' SEC Rule l Ob-S p rovides: I t shall be unlawful for any person, d irectly or i n directly, by the use of any means or i nstrumentality of i nterstate commerce, or of the mails or of any facility of any national securities exchange, ( a) To employ any device, scheme or artifice to defraud, (b) To make any untrue statement of a material fact or to omit to state a material fact n ecessary in order to make the statements made, in light of the circumstances under which they were made, not m isleading, or ( c ) To engage in any act, practice, or course of business which operates or would operate as a fraud or deceit upon any person, in connection with the purchase or sale of any security. 17 C . F.R. § 240. 1 0b-5 ( 199 1 ) . 22 O n e commentator describes t h i s process by stating that, in t h e Cady, R o berts opinion, " C hairman Cary discovered [Rule lOb -5] prohibited insider trad ing. " S tephen M . Bain bridge, The Insider Trading Prohibition: A Leg a l a n d Economic Enigma, 38 U FLA. L. REv. 35, 38 ( 1 986) (emphasis added) . 23 C h iarella v . U n i ted States, 445 U . S . 2 2 2 , 2 26-30 ( 1980 ) . 2 ' T h e original Senate b i l l t h a t formed the basis of t h e 1 934 Exchange Act prohibited the use of false or misleading statements and defined "statement" to include "any omission to state a material fact." S. 3420, 73d Cong., 2d Sess. § 9 ( a ) (4) ( 1 934). Congress omitted this provision from the final statute, deeming it superfluous. See H.R REP. No. 1383, 73d Cong. , 2d Sess. 32 ( 1934). 20 See, e.g., Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 228 ("One who fails to d isclose material i n formation prior to the consummation of a transaction commits fraud only when he is under a duty to do so."); Affiliated Ute C itizen s v. U n i ted States, 406 U . S . 1 28, 154 ( 1972) ("The obl igation to disclose and [ the] withholding of a material fact establish the requisite causation in fact. " ) . l I l I i l INSIDER TRADING 1 99 1 ] 1 87 yone unless he had a duty to disclose the information prior to trad ing. Under circumstances in which the trader has a duty to make such disclosure , trading in the absence of the disclosure constitutes securities fraud. 26 The requirement of a duty has resulted in some confusing judi cial rhetoric. The courts have developed two lines of reasoning whereby a trader may be said to breach a duty by trading on non public information. These lines of reasoning, which form two dis tinct bases for liability, are commonly known as the classical, or traditional, theory and the misappropriation theory. T H E CLASSICAL THEORY OF I N SIDER TRADING A. Classical insider trading theory has its roots in the regulation of trading by true corporate insiders.27 Insiders are privy to confiden tial inside information about their corporation by virtue of their corporate responsibilities. In addition, corporate insiders perform these responsibilities subject to a fiduciary duty which has its ori gins in statute and common law.28 In 1 96 1 , the SEC decided that the acquisition of nonpublic information by insiders gave rise to an obligation either to refrain from trading on that information or to disclose it.29 In the landmark decision In re Cady, Roberts & Co. , 3 0 26 It is generally assumed that an issuer itself cannot trade while in possession of material nonpublic i n formation. See, e.g. , Laventhall v. General Dynamics Corp. , 704 F.2d 407, 4 1 2 ( 8th Cir. ) , cert. denied, 464 U.S. 846 ( 1 983); Western Hemisphere Group v. Stan West Corp., [ 1984-85 Transfer B i n der] Fed. Sec. L . Rep. ( C C H ) �I 9 1 ,858, at 90,279 (S.D.N.Y. 1984); see a lso Donald C. Langevoort, Insider Trading and the Fiduciary Principle: A Pos t Ch iarella Rest a t e m e n t , 70 C A L L. R E v . 1 , 20-21 & n.77 ( 1 982) (comparing fiduciary obliga tions of issuer to those of corporate officers and employees) ; infra note 29 ( discussing cases in which courts found i n sider's fi d uciary d u ty to others justified liability ) . Under the Ameri can Law I nstitute's proposed Federal Secur ities Code, the term " i nsider" for purposes of i nsider trading obligations is defined to include the issuer. FED. SEc. ConE § 1 603 ( b ) ( 1 980) . 27 The term " insider" has not been defined b y statute or b y the Supreme Court. See 3 BROMBERG SECURITIES LAw § 7 . 4 ( 6 ) ( b ) at 1 80 - 8 1 & n . 1 6 9 . 1 ( 1 969). Section 1 6 ( b ) classifies d irectors, officers, and 10% stockholders as insiders, 15 U . S .C. § 78p ( a ) & ( b ) ( 1 988 ) , but its language is not necessarily applicable to Rule 10b-5. See M os s v. Nlorgan Stanley Inc., 7 1 9 F . 2 d 5, 1 0 n.8 (2d C i r . 1 983) ("Ordinarily, 'insi ders' i nclude such corporate figures a s d i rec tors and vice presidents, persons who have access to confidential corporate i n formation and therefore owe a duty to a corporation's shareholders not to trade on that information. "), cert. denied, 465 U . S . 1 025 ( 1984 ) . 28 See, e.g. , WILLIAM L. C ARY & MELVIN A EISENBERG. CASES AND MATERIALS ON CoRPORA TIONS 47 1-548 (6th ed. 1 990 ) ( describing development of common- law and statutory fiduci ary duties of insiders) . '" in re C a d y Roberts & Co., 40 S.E.C. 907, 9 1 1 ( 1 96 1 ) . Prior to 1961, there had been a . , [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 188 the Commission held that corporate insiders who receive inside in formation by virtue of their p osition have a duty to disclose the information to persons with whom they deal ( or to the public at large) or to refrain from trading. 31 A failure to adhere to the "dis close or abstain" rule constituted fraud and hence violated Rule lOb-5.32 The courts have accepted the classical theory of insider trad ing.33 In Chiare lla u . United States, the Supreme Court adopted the Cady, Roberts rationale that insider trading can violate Rule lOb-5 as a fraudulent omission or fai lure to disclose but explained that liability must be premised on a duty to disclose.34 The C ourt few court decisions that found i n s i d e r trading i llegal as a violation o f e i t h e r R u l e 1 0b-5 o r state comm o n - law doctri n es . One of the b e s t k n o w n is Speed v. Transamerica Corp., 99 F . S u p p . 8 0 8 (D. Del. 1 951), i n w h i c h C h i e f Justice Leahy permitted recovery u n d e r Rule 1 0 b - 5 b y m i nority stockholders of t h e Axton -Fisher Tobacco Company w h o w e r e bought out b y the majority stockholder, Transamerica, a t a n unfairly l o w price. Transamerica had i n for mation, which i t did not disclose to the other stockholders, that Axton-Fisher's tobacco in ventory was greatly undervalued. /d. at 8 1 2. Speed was not technically an insider trading case; liability was premised on a fraudulent failure to d isclose, which was actionable because of Transamerica's fiduciary duties as majority stockholder. Id. at 828. Additionally, the transaction i n Speed was a face-to-face transaction so there was n o n eed for the court to consider the general duties of a n insider to the marketplace based o n the possession of superior i n formation. In general, j udicial decisions during this p e riod i mposed insider trading l iability only in circumstances that involved face-to-face transactions be tween the insider and those to whom the insider owed fiduciary duties, typically stockhold ers. Bainbridge, supra note 22, a t 3 7 - 38. See also In re Ward La France Truck Corp . , 13 S . E . C . 373, 381 (1943), in \vh i c h , i n one of the first SEC opinions i n terpreting Rule 10b-5, the Commission reached the same conclu sion as the Transamerica court and held that insiders who purchased stock o n behalf of the issuer without d isclosin g material i n formation to the stockholders with whom they traded violated the rule. Aga i n , l iability was based on the fiduciary obligations of the issuer and i ts officers to stockholders. "The failure to [ disclose] placed shareholders at an u n fa i r d isadvan tage in dealing with their own corporation and those i n control . " !d. at 380- 8 1 . ' 0 40 S . E . C . 907, 9 1 1 ( 1 96 1 ) . :n Jd. :\2 I d. at 9 1 :3. "" See, e.g. , SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 401 F.2d 8:33, 848-49 ( 2d Cir. 1 968) (en bane) (" [A] nyone in possession of material i nside i n formation m ust either d isclose it . . . or . . . must abstain from trading in or recommending the securities . . . ") , cert. denied, 394 U . S . 9 7 6 ( 1 969). 3' 445 U.S. 222 (1980). Notably, according to the Supreme Court, Chiarella was the first case in which criminal l iability was i mposed upon a defendant for insider trading. !d. at 235 n.20. Chiarella involved the prosecution of a financial printer who deciphered the identities of targets of upcoming takeover bids from documents h e received for printing. W ithout dis closing the information he had obtai ned, C hiarella purchased the stock of the target compa nies before the takeover attempts were made public. United States v. Chiarella, 588 F.2d 1358, L162 (2d Cir. 1978), reu'd, 445 U . S . 222 (1980). . 1 99 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 1 89 stated that this duty may arise "from a relation�hip of trust and confidence between parties to a transaction."35 It concluded that this type of relationship exists between corporate insiders and stockholders, based on the insiders' obligation to put the stock holders' welfare before their own.36 The Court consequently re versed Chiarella's conviction on the grounds that he neither was a corporate insider nor owed any duties to the stockholders of the corporation in whose stock he traded.37 One obvious difficulty with the classical theory is that it fails to explain why the fiduciary relationship between insiders and the corporation gives rise to a duty in the financial marketplace to speak. In other words , why is trading by a corporate fiduciary de ceptive, and who is deceived? Some scholars have attempted to base the insider's duty to disclose on common-law principles of agency. 38 A corporate insider receives inside information in order to effectuate his role as agent for the corporation. 39 Agency law prohibits an agent from obtaining a personal benefit in the course of serving as agent.40 Under traditional agency rules, any profit an 3° Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 230. The Court stated that a corporate i nsider owes a duty to present stockholders because of his fiduciary obligations to such stockholders ; thus, the i nsider who purchases stock from such stockholders on the basis of i nside i n formation has breached this fiduciary duty. !d. at 227-28. The Court concluded that it would be irrational to allow insiders to abuse their position by selling stock based on inside information , even though sales would not breach any duty to existing stockholders. !d. at 227 n.8. 3 7 Id. at 231-35. The Court expressly rejected the argument that anyone who has i nside i n formation owes a general Cady, R o berts duty to the marketplace. For a detailed analysis of the opinions i n Chiarella and the bases for regulation espoused by the various Justices, see Frank H. Easterbrook, Insider Trading, Secret Agen ts, Evidentiary Privileges and t h e Produ ction o f Information, 1981 SuP. C T . REv. 309, 314-30. "" E.g. , Langevoort, s upra note 26, at 1 9-21. 39 See James D. Cox, Insider Trading a n d Contracting: A Critical Response to t h e Chi cago Sch o o l , 1986 DuKE L.J. 628, 659 ( noting expectation of stockholders that insider will concentrate on developing corporation's i nterests rather than his own private investment agenda). '0 See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF AGENCY § 388 & cmt. C (1957); see a lso RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF AGENCY § 395 (1957). Unless otherwise agreed, an agent is subject to a duty to the principal n o t to use or to communicate i n formation con fidentially given him by the principal or acquired by him during the course of or on account of his agency or i n viola tion of his d u ties as agent, i n competition with or to the i njury of the principal, v n h i s own a c c o u n t or on b e h a lf o f anoth er, a lthough such information does not relate to the transaction in which he is then employed , un less the i n forma tion is a matter of general knowledge. !d. ( emphasis added). This common- law rule is designed to remove the agent's temptation 36 1 90 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 agent receives i n the course of his agen cy is received in trust for the principal . 4 1 Applying agency principles t o insider trading is problematic, however, because agency law does not generate an obligation to the trading counterparty or to the market. R ather, agency law s uggests that a corporate insider is unjustly enriched by making use of cor porate information for his personal benefit and that any trading profits are rightfully the property of the owner of the informa tion-the corporation.42 This unjust enrichment takes place, though, whether or not the insider discloses the infor.m ation prior to trading. M ore importantly, unjust enrichment is not the legal equivalent of deception. An agent who receives a personal benefit and thereby enriches himself unjustly does not necessarily deceive his principal.43 Thus, the agency analogy neither supports the Cady, Roberts duty to disclose or abstain nor explains how the breach of that duty violates section 1 0 ( b ) . Another possible explanation for the Cady, Roberts duty i s a level-playing-field notion of the securities markets. This approach assumes investors are entitled to equal access to securities i nfor mation.44 Any informational inequality based on unequal access, to act contrary to his principal's i n terests i n order to obtain a personal benefit. See A llison G . Anderson , Conflicts of Interest: Efficiency, Fairness a n d Corporate Struct u re, 2 5 UCLA L. REv. 738, 758-60 ( 1978) ( discussing fi d uciary d uties as safeguards ) ; Gareth Jones, Unjust Enrichment and the Fiduciary 's Duty of Loyalty, 84 L A W Q REv. 4 7 2 , 486-87 ( 1 968) (dis cussi n g public policy issues regard i n g such a rule ) . " E.g., Tarnowski v. Resop, 5 1 N . W . 2 d 8 0 1 , 8 0 2 ( M i n n . 195 2 ) . T h e extension of t h i s prin ciple to corporate law has resulted in the development of the corporate-opportunity doc trine, under which a corporate insider who receives a business opportunity i n the course of his employme n t may not appropriate the opportunity for his persona l gain. T h e most fa mous application of the corporate-opportu n i ty doctrin e i n volved the case of G u t h v. Loft, I n c . , 5 A . 2d 503, 5 1 1 (Del. 1939) , in which C harles Guth, the president of L oft, a m anufac turer and distributor of fountain beverages, attempted to acquire and explo i t the P epsi-Cola formula and trademark for h i s persona l benefit. The Delaware Supreme Court held that the opportunity belonged to the company a n d could not be taken by Guth personally. !d. at 5 1 5. Even i n cases involving the m isappropriation of a corporate opportun ity, however, the i n s i d er's conduct m a y be ratified by t h e corporation. E.g . , K l i n icki v. Lundgren, 6 9 5 P . 2 d 906, 920 (Or. 1985) . ' " See supra note 40 ( discussi n g common law of agency a s reflected i n Restatement (Sec ond) of Agency ) . "' S e e RK'TATEMENT (SECOND) OF T R U STS § 2 0 3 ( 1 959) (stating trustee i s accountable for any profit made by h i m arising out of administration of trust, even if p rofit d oes not result from trustee's breach of trust) . According to the Supreme Court, the SEC has argued for a parity-of-i n formation stan d ard. See, e.g , Dirks v . SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 657 ( 1983) ( " [ T ] h e SEC's theory of tippee liabil·I I 1 I l l 1 1 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 191 such as the receipt o f inside information, compels a duty t o dis close or abstain. The deception, under this approach, is of others trading in the security. The level-playing-field concept is based on the view that traders should not be able to take advantage of infor mation they know cannot lawfully be obtained by others.45 The duty to disclose or abstain is premised on principles of fairness: it is unfair for corporate insiders to trade on the basis of information to which they have access solely because of their p osition as insiders. 46 The third potential source for the insider's duty lies in the cor poration's own duty of disclosure. Trading47 by the corporation it self, while in possession of material nonpublic information , would constitute securities fraud because of the issuer's duty, under the federal securities laws, to disclose all material inform ation relevant to investors before trading.48 When corporate insiders obtain infor mation from the corporation, which itself may not lawfully trade, they arguably inherit the corporation's duty to disclose. The foregoing discussion focuses on the absence of an identifi able source for the Cady, Roberts duty. The second problem with the classical approach is its failure to articulate the beneficiary of that duty, i . e . , the person(s) to whom the duty is owed. Even if one ity [in both Dirks and Chiarel l a ] appears rooted in the idea that the antifraud provisions require equal i n formation among all traders . " ) . Strictly speaking, this characterization is not true. No one woul d suggest that all players i n the investment markets have equal i n forma tion. See Jonathan R . Macey, From Fairness t o Contract: The New Direction of the Ru les Against Insider Trading, 13 H o FSTRA L. REv. 9, 1 6 - 1 7 ( 1 984) (discussing i nevitable advan tage of one party over the other i n a securities trade) . The level -playing-field standard is based on equal access to i n formation-a parity-of-access standard. See SEC v . Texas Gulf Sulphur Co. , 401 F.2d 833, 848-49 ( 2d Cir. 1 968) (en bane) ("The Rule is based in policy on the justifiable expectation of the securities marketplace that all investors trading on imper sonal exchanges have relatively equa l access to materia! information.") ( emphasis added ) , cert denied, 394 U.S. 976 ( 1 969). ' 6 This concept appears to be the basis of the Cady, Roberts decision. See Brudney, supra note 1 3 , at 353-54. 4 6 More broadly stated, i t may be viewed as u n fair for anyone to trade on the basis of information that is not publicly available. See infra notes 185- 1 94 and accompanying text. 47 The disclosure obligations of a nontrading corporation are not clear. The courts have suggested that, under certain circumstances, even a nontrading corporation may be l i able for fai lure to disclose material developme n ts that would have a significant impact on stock price. See, e.g. , Basic, Inc. v. Levinson, 485 U . S . 224, 230-41 ( 1 988) (discussin g when corpo ration must d isclose preliminary corporate-merger d iscussions and suggesting that failure to discl ose such discussions may constitute fraudulent omission ) . 4 6 See supra note 26. 192 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 26: 1 7 9 accepts the premise that a corporate insider has a common-law duty to abstain from using inside information for personal trading, it does not necessarily follow that the duty is to the market. The fiduciary duty viewed by the Chiare lla C ourt as the source of the insider's obligation to disclose or abstain is a duty to the corpora tion, not to the market at large.49 The breach of a fiduciary duty to the issuer, however, does not obviously constitute the deception re quired for a violation of section 1 0 ( b ) . Moreover , the case law under section 1 0 ( b ) makes clear that every violation of a common law duty does not give rise to a violation of the statute's antifraud provisions.5° Congress clearly did not intend, through the enact ment of section 1 0 ( b ) , to federalize common-law doctrines of fidu ciary duty.51 Accordingly, the breach of duty must, in some way, implicate the p olicies behind the federal securities laws. The violation of an agency-law based principle of fiduciary duty fails to do so. If the insider's trading is wrongful because of his fiduciary obligations to the corporation , it is not therefore deceptive or fraudulent. The corporation has not been deceived in connection with the p urchase or sale of a security. The courts have attempted to deal with this problem by inferring a fiduciary duty to the corporation's stock holders. 52 A corporate insider has a direct fiduciary d uty to the corporation ; he also has a fiduciary duty to the corporation's stock holders. When an insider trades with stockholders without disclos ing his superior information, the insider has deceived them in vio- 49 See C h iarella v. United States, 445 U . S . 2 2 2 , 2 3 1 -32 & n. 1 4 ( 1980) (rej ecting court of appeals' theory that Chiarella's position or access generated duty to d isclose i n formation to others i n market) . 60 See, e.g. , Santa Fe I ndus. v. Green, 430 U . S . 462, 473-74 ( 1 977) ( holding statute bars only "manipulative or deceptive" conduct). " See id. at 479 ( rejecting application of securities laws that would have federal courts applying a " ' federal fi duciary principle' under Rule 1 0 b - 5 " ) . " E.g . , Chiarella, 4 4 5 U .S . at 2 2 7 . This reasoning suggests that i n s i d e r trading i n debt securities would not violate Rule 10b-5, at least under classical insider trading theory. The applicability of the prohibition to trading i n debt securities has not been d e fi n itively ad dressed by the courts. See SEC Staff Examining Jun k Bonds for Insider Trading, Breeden Says, 23 Sec. Reg. & L. Rep. ( B N A ) No. 1 5 , at 525 (April 1 2 , 1 99 1 ) (quoting Chairman B reeden's statement to Senate Banking Comm ittee C hairman Donald Riegle that applicable theories have not yet been tested i n courts ) . Some opinions appear to have assumed, with out analysis, that such trading is prohibited. See, e.g. , U n ited States v. Milken, 7 59 F . Supp. 109, 1 22-23 (S.D.N.Y. 1 990) ( fi nding defendant d i d not receive material nonpublic i n forma t i o n but assu mir.g t h a t l i a b i l i t y could be b a s e d u p o n defendant's trades i n corp o rate bonds ) . 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 193 lation of this fiduciary duty.53 It is not immediately obvious why the existence of a corporate law fiduciary duty makes the insider's trading with the corpora tion's stockholders deceptive. Apparently, the deception stems from a higher duty of disclosure or a duty of absolute fairness aris ing from the fiduciary relationship. For example, if the fiduciary relationship generates a duty of objective candor, the stockholder, as beneficiary of this duty, may expect that when an insider trades with stockholders, the insider has disclosed all material informa tion. If the insider does not disclose all material facts , the stock holder is deceived. One legal source for a greater duty of disclosure in the fiduciary relationship is the special facts doctrine/4 an exception to the gen eral principle that there is no duty of absolute disclosure.'>5 If the parties to a transaction stand in some confidential or fiduciary re lationship, dealings between them require the "utmost good faith, and full and fair disclosure of all material facts. "06 An alternative source for a greater duty of disclosure is the law of trusts. P articularly in older cases, the position of a corporate insider has been analogized to that of a trustee. 57 The law of trusts governs transactions between fiduciary and beneficiary. In such transactions, it imposes upon the trustee a duty of the " utmost fairness" to the beneficiary, including disclosure of all information known to the trustee. 58 Again, the stockholder as beneficiary would "'' See Chiarella , 445 U.S. at 2 27 ( " [T ] he relationship between a corporate insider and the s tockholders of his corporation gives rise to a disclosure obligation. " ) . " S e e id. a t 228 n . 1 0 ; Langevoort, supra note 26, a t 4 - 5 . ' � S e e W. P A G E KEETON E T AL., P ROSSER A N D KEETON O N T H E L A w O F ToRTS § 1 0 6 , a t 7 3 7 3 8 ( 5th e d . 1 984) (noting t h a t modern cases find no general duty t o d isclose material facts ) . 06 Id. at 738-39. Traditionally, the special-facts doctrine did not apply to transactions that took place on organized stock exchanges. See, e.g. , HENRY G . MANNE, I NSIDER TRADING AND THE S TO C K MARKET 23-24 ( 1 966) . 67 See, e.g. , O liver v. O liver, 1 1 8 Ga. 362, 367, 45 S.E. 232, 234 ( 1 903) (holding that officer or director is " a quasi trustee as to the shareholder's i nterest i n the shares"); Stewart v. H arris, 77 P. 277, 279 ( Kan. 1 904) ("The managing officers of a corporation are not only trustees i n relation to the corporate entity and the corporate property, but they are also to some extent and i n many respects trustees of the corporate shareholders . " ) ; People ex rel. Manice v. Powel l , 94 N.E. 634, 637 ( N . Y . 1 9 1 1 ) ("The relation of the directors to the stock holders is essentially that of trustee and cestui que trus t . " ) . '" S e e GEORGE T BoGERT, TRUSTS § 9 6 , at 3 4 8 (6th ed. 1 987 ) : If a trustee enters into a transaction with a beneficiary relating t o the inter est of the beneficiary under the trust, the trustee owes the benefi ciary a duty to display the utmost fairness, which ordinarily involves disclosure to t h e ben- 1 94 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 26: 1 7 9 expect the insider t o disclose all material facts unknown t o the stockholder. Finally, the insider's duty can be viewed not as a disclosure obli gation but as a duty of overall or objective fairness. This duty may be linked to the corporate -law duty of loyalty, under which an in sider may not compete with the corporation or engage i n transac tions in which he has a personal interest unless those transactions are objectively fair to the corporation and its stockholders. 59 Transactions in which the insider has a personal stake present a special risk that the insider will abuse his fiduciary position. 6 0 Under this standard of objective fairness, an insider who fails to disclose material information prior to trading with stockholders has misled those stockholders into entering an u nfair transaction. The foregoing explanations provide a logical basis for finding that corporate stockholders have been deceived when an insider buys their stock ( or sells them additional stock) without disclosing information obtained by virtue of the insider's p osition. Although the use of the fiduciary relationship to extend the insider's duties to a class of intended beneficiaries of the securities laws is widely accepted,61 it applies only to trades between an insider and stock holders of the insider's corporation. It is thus one-sided in opera tion. A corporate insider who purchases stock is trading with pre sent stockholders and arguably defrauds those to whom he owes a fiduciary obligation. On the other hand , a corporate insider who sells stock is dealing with someone who has no current relationship with the corporation. In this second case, the fiduciary obligations of the insider to the corporation generate no duty to disclose or abstain.62 eficiary of a l l relev a n t facts which are unknown to the beneficiary . . . . The doctrine applies to a l l fiduciaries and also to persons in a confidential relationship . . . . (emphasis added ) . •• See, e.g , Lewis v . S.L. & E . , Inc., 6 2 9 F . 2 d 764, 768-70 ( 2 d C i r . 1 980) ; Scott v. M u l t i Amp Corp . , 3 8 6 F. S u p p . 4 4 , 6 8 ( D . N.J. 1974 ) . 60 See Anderson, supra note 40, at 760-61 ( noting situations in which l i kelihood of cheat ing is particularly great ) . 6 1 Chiarella v. U n i ted S tates, 445 U.S. 222, 227 n.8 ( 1980 ) . 6 � T h e Supreme Court's o n ly effort at addressing this dilemma is contained i n foo tnote eight of Chiarell a , in which the CoUit c ites the reasoning of Judge Learned Hand that " i t would b e a sorry distinction to allow [ th e insider] to use the advantage o f h i s position t o i nduce t h e buyer i n t o t h e position of a beneficiary although he was forbidden to d o so once the buyer had become one . " !d . ( q uoting G ratz \·. C laughton, 187 F.2d 46, 49 (2d C ir. ) , cert . 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 1 95 Moreover , Rule lOb-5 requires that the fraud occur in connec tion with the sale or purchase of securities.63 This requirement has two elements: the fraud must affect the financial m arketplace,64 and the plaintiff must be a defrauded purchaser or seller.65 It is the latter element that is of significance here, for as the Court found in Blue Chip Stamps v . Manor Drug Stores , Rule lOb-5 is aimed only at "injury suffered 'in connection with the purchase or sale' of se curi ties. "66 Indeed, the Blue Chip Court specifically found that two classes of p laintiffs to whom corporate insiders owed fiduciary du ties lacked standing to recover under lOb-5 for the insiders' fraud because there was an insufficient connection between the fraud and a securities transaction.67 Thus, in B lue Chip, the C ourt specifically rej ected the notion that every fraud or breach of fiduciary duty practiced by a corpo rate insider upon shareholders constitutes securities fraud. The Court restricted the class of actionable claims under lOb-5 to those in which the fraud resulted in the purchase or sale of stock by the victim. 68 As the next section will demonstrate, this connection be- denied, 3 4 1 U . S . 9 2 0 ( 19 5 1 ) ) . A lthough the distinction m a y w e l l be a "sorry" o n e , i t is d i ffi cult t o understand h o w this reasoning gives rise t o a duty by insiders not t o s e l l their stock on the basis of inside information. Importantly, the opinion of Judge Hand to which the Chiarella Court refers addressed the constitutionality of section 1 6 ( b ) , not the obligations imposed by section 1 0 ( b ) . See Gra t z , 187 F.2d at 49. 63 17 C . F. R . § 240. 1 0b-5 ( 199 1 ) . •• A s Judge Friendly explained: The purpose of § 1 0 ( b ) and Rule lOb-5 is to protect persons who are deceived in securities transactions-to make sure that buyers of securities get what they think they are getting and that sellers of securities are not tricked i n to parting with something for a price known to the buyer to be inadequate or for a consideration known to the buyer not to be what it purports to be. Chemical Bank v . Arthur Andersen & Co., 726 F.2d 930, 943 (2d Cir.) (emphasis added), cert. d e n i e d , 469 U . S . 884 ( 1 984) ; s e e a lso Hemming v . Alfin Fragrances, Inc., 690 F . S).ipp. 239, 244 (S.D.N.Y. 1 988) (distinguishing certain consumer-oriented statements as not invok ing antifraud provisions of federal securities laws because not directed to i nvestors) . 65 S e e B lue Chip Stamps v. Manor D r u g S tores, 4 2 1 U .S. 723, 755 ( 1 97 5 ) (refusing stand ing to defrauded i nvestors who did not trade on basis of misrepresentations) . • • ! d . at 733; cf. U n i ted States v . Naftalin, 4 4 1 U . S . 768, 772-76 ( 1979) (refusing t o limit application of section 1 7 ( a) ( l ) of Securities Act of 1 933 to frauds injuring i nvestors, on basis that i nvestor protection was not sole purpose of Securities Act ) . 6 7 The Court's holding i n Blue Chip denies standi ng t o present stockholders o f a corpora tion who are defrauded through management m isrepresentations into not selling their stock and to stockholders ( and creditors) who suffer a loss in the value of their stock as a result of the insiders' fraudulent practices. See Blue Chip , 4 2 1 U . S . at 737-38. "8 ! d . at 723. O n this basis the Southern D istrict of New York dism issed insider trading charges i n Uni t e d S t a t es u. Newman, holding that the defendant could not be l iable for 1 96 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26: 1 79 tween the fraud and the securities transaction has been completely eviscerated in cases applying the misappropriation theory.69 Even under the classical doctrine of insider trading, however, the con nection between the insider's fraud and the victim 's i njury is not altogether clear. Although courts have found that trading by an insider or tippee furnishes the necessary p ur chase or sale to satisfy the " in connec tion with" requirement, they have not required any tie between the securities transaction and the breach of duty. 7 0 The problem lies in distinguishing between an insider who sells confidential cor porate i nformation to a competitor and one who sells such infor mation to a prospective trader. The misappropriation of informa tion from the company is the same, as is the breach of the insider's fiduciary duty. Indeed, the damage to the company is likely to be greater in the former case. Yet, only the second situation violates insider trading law, and that violation results from the fortuity that the recipient of the information intends to use it in the securi ties markets. In addition, unlike traditional securities fraud, there is no direct relationship between the corporate insider's breach of a duty-the decision to engage in insider trading-and the transaction that causes harm to other stockholders-the ' ignorant' trade.71 The cor- insider trading unless he defrauded a p urchaser or seller of securities. Uni ted States v . New man, 664 F . 2d 1 2 , 1 9 ( 2d Cir. 1 98 1 ) , c e r t . denied, 464 U.S. 863 ( 1 983 ) . The Second Circuit reversed the dismissal. !d. 6 9 For a d iscussion of the misappropriation theory, see infra notes 80- 1 2 9 and accompany ing text. 70 The insider's ( or tippee's) trading is the securities transaction w i th which the fraud is connected. See, e.g . , SEC v. Materia, 745 F.2d 197, 203 ( 2d Cir. 1 984), cert. denied, 471 U . S . 1 0 5 3 ( 1985) ; Newman, 664 F . 2d at 1 8 . 7 1 Cf. infra note 185 ( discussing commentators' v iews of whether insider trading d irectly h arms contemporaneous traders ) . Some commentators have argued that insider trad ing causes market makers and specialists to adjust the spread for stocks i n which insider trading is l ikely. E.g . , W il liam J. Carney, Signaling and Causation in Insider Trading, 36 CATH. U . L . REV. 8 6 3 , 888-9 1 ( 1 987 ) . If insider trading i nduces a n y trading, it i s l ikely t o i nduce copycat trades b y investors who, although not privy to the inside i n formation directly, hope to take indirect advantage of such i n formation by duplicating the trades of insiders. This process has been described as "trade decod ing.'' See Gilson & K raakman, supra note 1 1 , at 5 7 3 ( describing widespread trading practice by uninformed traders of duplicating trading by insiders based on assump tion that insiders are l i kely to possess valuable information) . The trading by statutory corporate insiders (officers, d irectors, and 10% stockholders) as reported to the government through the filing of Schedule 1 6A is made available to the 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 197 porate insiders who purchased stock on the basis of inside informa tion in SEC v. Texas G u lf Sulphur Co. ,72 for example, did not in duce present stockholders to sell their stock but simply bought stock for themselves before any public announcement of the dis covery of extraordinarily rich mineral deposits.73 Those stockhold ers who decided contemporaneously to sell did so based on extra neous factors and in ignorance of the existence of insider trading. Their decision to sell the stock for a price that did not reflect the mineral deposit opportunity was the d irect cause of their loss and was, presumably, a decision they would have made even if the in siders had stayed out of the market.74 Accordingly, while the insid ers may have breached a duty to the company by making a per sonal profit with corporate inform ation, it is difficult to see any relationship between that breach and the harm suffered by the selling stockholders, who supposedly were the defrauded victims.75 There is another problem with premising the fraudulent aspect of insider trading on the insiders' fiduciary duties to the corpora tion's stockholders: the premise is not implicated unless trading is effected by a traditional insider and the insider trades in the secur ities of his own corporation. For example, an insider, by virtue of his inside position in corporation A, receives material inside infor- public on a monthly basis i n the Official S um mary of Security Transactions and Holdings, printed by the U.S. Government P rinting Office in Washington, D . C . A n umber of invest ment newsletters, books, and da tabases are marketed on the premise that merely copying the reported trading activities of corporate insiders is l ikely to produce superior returns. E.g. , VICKERS WEEKLY INSIDER REPORT; THE INSIDERS' CHRONICLE ( a weekly publication of American Banker-Bond Buyer edited by William Mehlman); AARON B . FEIGE:-J & DoN CHRISTENSEN. INVESTING WITH THE INSIDERS LEGALLY ( 1 988) ; cf. Dan G i voly & Dan Palmon, Insider Trading and the Exp lo i t a t ion of Inside Informa t ion: Some Empirical Evidence, 58 J. Bus. 69, 71 ( 1 985) (suggesting that, because of copycat effect generated when insiders trade, such trading may generate abnormal returns in absence of any m isuse of inside information ) . 7 2 4 0 1 F.2d 833 ( 2 d Cir. 1 968) ( e n bane) , cert. denied, 394 U . S . 976 ( 1 969) . '3 !d. at 847, 852-57. '' See Carney, supra note 7 1 , at 886-9 1 (finding no causal relations h i p between unde tected in s i d e r trading and harm to particular investors ) . " Indeed, i t i s n o t Clear t h a t Texas G u l f Sulphur could itself have traded stock during the time period in question, being in possession of material information that it had a duty to disclose t o stockholders i f it traded. See supra notes 26- 29. Thus, the d irect victim of the insiders' breach of duty cou ld not suffer an injury through engaging in securities transac tions. This d ivorce of the duty breached from the harm suffered is carried to an extreme by the conte mporaneous traders provision of the Insider Trading and Securities Fraud En forcement Act of 1 988, § 20A , 15 U . S . C . § 78t - 1 ( 1 988) . Section 20A permits investors who trade con t e m poraneously with an i nsider to recover a private damage award. !d. [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 198 m ation concerning corporation B , such a s the fact that corporation A is about to terminate its long-term sup plier/purchaser relation ship with corporation B or that corporation A is planning a tender offer for the stock of corporation B. Knowing that disclosure of this information will have a substantial effect on the price of B's securities, the insider trades i n the securities of corporation B. Under the principles described above , the insider has not commit ted securities fraud. Whether the insider buys or sells, his transac tion is not with the stockholders of corporation A, to which he owes a fiduciary duty, but with the stockholders or future stock holders of corporation B, to which no such duty is owed.76 Trading of this type is frequently described as " outsi der trad ing, " so denominated because the traders are outsiders with re spect to the issuer of the securities they trade.77 Outsider trading commonly occurs in connection with tender offers and other take over transactions. Insiders of the acquiring company, for example, knowing of the impending tender offer, may purchase stock in the target company prior to public announcement of the offer. Out sider trading also has been used to describe trading by persons who are not traditional insiders but perhaps could be described as market insiders based on their regular access to confidential infor mation likely to affect market prices. This group includes securi ties analysts , reporters , and financial printers. Prohibition of outsider trading requires a theory of liability that does not depend on a fiduciary relationship between the trader and the issuer of the securities traded. It therefore demonstrates the limitations of the classical theory. These limitations are illustrated by the Court's finding in Chiare l la that the Cady, Ro berts duty to disclose or abstain could not support Chiarella's conviction because he had no fiduciary duty to the companies in whose stock he traded.78 This decision generated dissatisfaction with the classical theory as the sole basis for imposing liability for insider trading. Although Chiare l la was a setba-ck , the SEC and the courts, most 76 See P h i l lips & Zutz, s u pra note 5 , at 85 ( a rgu i ng that fiduciary d u ty sta n d a r d res u l ts in inabil ity to apply section l O ( b ) and Rule lOb-5 to persons trading stock of one company while e m p loyed at another company) . based on information learned " See SEC v. C lark, 9 15 F.2d 439, 443 (9th who are ne ither i n s i d ers of t h e c om pan i es Cir. 1 990) ( d e fi n i ng " o uts i d e r s ' ' a s " p e rsons whose shares a;-e being tra ded, nor t i ppees o f such insiders " ) . 78 Chiarella v. U n i ted States, 445 U . S . 222, 232-33 ( 1980) r 1991] INSIDER TRADING 199 notably the Second C ircuit,79 found within Chiare lla the seeds of an alternative approach to insider trading: the misappropriation theory. B. THE MISAPPROPRIATI ON THEORY The misappropriation theory bases liability on the breach of a duty other than the insider's fiduciary duty to his corporation.80 As the Second C ircuit explained in SEC v. Ma teria, a person who mis appropriates or steals confidential information defrauds the source of the information.81 It concluded that the use of confidential cor porate information for personal gain by an outsider is misappropri ation. In Ma teria, the court held that a financial printer who had engaged in wrongdoing similar to that of Chiarella had defrauded his employer, not the target companies. This fraud on the source was found by the court to be a sufficient predicate for an insider 7 9 SEC v. Materia, 745 F.2d 1 97 , 201 (2d Cir. 1 9 84 ) , cert. denied, 471 U.S. 1 053 ( 1985 ) . Thus far, t h e only other circuits t o adopt t h e misappropriation theory a r e t h e Third, Roth berg v. Rosenbloom, 7 7 1 F.2d 8 1 8 , 824 (3d Cir. 1985 ) ; the Seventh, SEC v . Cherif, 933 F.2d 403, 410 (7th Cir. 1 99 1 ) , cert. denied, No. 9 1 -605, 1 992 U . S . LEXIS 658 ( U. S . Jan. 27, 1992 ) ; and t h e N i n t h , SEC v. C l a r k , 9 1 5 F.2d 4 3 9 , 4 5 3 ( 9 t h Cir. 1 990). T h e theory has been e m ployed in several other circuits a t t h e d istrict court l e v e l . S e e , e.g. , SEC v. H urton, 7 3 9 F. Supp. 704, 705 ( D . Mass. 1990 ) ; SEC v. Peters, 735 F . Supp. 1 505, 1520 (D. Kan. 1 990) ; U n i ted States v. E lliott, 7 1 1 F. Supp. 425, 4 3 1 ( N . D . Ill. 1989 ) . 80 The Ninth C ircuit has described the elements of the m isappropriation theory as follows: Rule 10b-5 i s violated when a person ( 1 ) misappropriates material nonpublic information (2) by breaching a duty arising out of a relationship of trust and confidence and (3) uses that information i n a securities transaction, (4) regard less of whether he owed any duties to the shareholders of the traded stock. Clark , 915 F.2d at 443. 81 Ma teria, 745 F.2d at 201 ; s e e also Chiarella, 445 U.S. at 239-40 ( Burger, C.J., dissent ing) (applying duty to d isclose o r abstain whenever informational advantage is obtained "by some unlawful means" ) . Ma t eria involved the same factual scenario as Chiarella; notwith standing efforts by clients to keep the identities of takeover targets confidential, Materia, a copyholder for a financial printer, was able to ascertain the identities of the targets. Materia p urchased stock i n the target companies and made substantial profits. Unlike C hiarella, Materia was charged with trading on the basis of information that had been m isappropri ated from his employer. lvfa t eria , 745 F.2d at 1 99-200. lvfa teria was not the first Second Circuit decision to adopt the misappropriation t heory. The concept that ins ider trading l iabi l i ty could be p redicated on the defendant's defraud ing the source of the information was first adopted by that court in United States v. Newman, 664 F.2d 12, 18 (2d Cir. 1981 ) , cert. denied, 464 U.S. 863 ( 1 983 ) . The Second C i rcuit has continued to apply t he misappropriation theory. See, e.g. , United States v . Grossman. 843 F.2d 78, 85-86 ( 2ci Cir. 1988), cert. d e n i e d , 488 U . S . 1 040 ( 1 989 ) . GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 200 [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 trading conviction. 82 Fraud under the misappropriation theory is not premised upon a duty to disclose or abstain. Indeed, the Ma teria court explicitly rejected the argument that insider trading liability must be based on a duty to disclose.83 Instead, the court found that the misappro priation of confidential information which defrauds the source84 satisfies Rule 1 0b-5's requirement that the fraud operate " on any person . ' ' 8 15 The separate opinions in Chiarella contain the seeds of the mis appropriation theory. Justice Stevens's concurring opinion , which provided the crucial fifth vote in Chiare lla , explained that the Court had not addressed whether Chiarella's breach of a duty of silence to his employer could serve as a basis of liability. 86 Simi larly, both Chief Justice Burger's dissenting opinion and Justice Brennan's opinion concurring in the judgment stressed that a trader could violate Rule lOb-5 by trading on the basis of informa tion that was improperly obtained.87 The Second C ircuit seized upon the language in these opinions and expanded it. Eschewing any requirement that the trader actually steal inside information, courts have permitted prosecution under the misappropriation the ory whenever the trader obtains or uses inside information in breach of a " fiduciary or similar duty of trust and confidence. "88 The requirement of "a relationship of trust and confidence " re flects the S upreme Court's language in Chiare l la.89 82 Materia, 7 4 5 F.2d at 203. 83 I d. 84 at 203. v . Clark , 9 1 5 F.2d 439, 447 ( " [ O ] utsider trading liability is premised on the common law principle that when a fiduciary profits from confidential i n for mation that he had received because of his fiduciary status, he breaches a l egal duty to the person or entity that e ntrusted him with the i nformation.") (quoting U n i ted S tates v. Reed, 6 0 1 F. Supp. 685, 700 (S.D.N. Y. ) , rev 'd in part on other grounds, 773 F . 2d 477 ( 2d Cir. !d. at 2 0 1 -02; see a lso SEC 1 985) ) . 8' Ma teria , 7 4 5 86 F . 2d a t 2 0 1 . Chiarella , 4 4 5 U.S. at 238 ( Stevens, J . , concurring) . 87 See id. at 239 ( B rennan, J . , concurring) (stating that Rule I Ob-5 is violated whenever person improperly obtains or converts nonpublic i n formation to his own use and then trades on i t ) ; id. at 243-45 ( Burger, C . J . , dissenting) ( i n formation obtained through theft, conver sion, or other un lawful means cannot be used as basis for trading) . ss U n ited States v. Willis, 737 F. Supp. 269, 2 7 2 ( S . D . N . Y . 1990). "" See Ch iarella , 445 U.S. at 230 ( predicating liability under section l O ( b ) for fraudulent omission "upon a duty to disclose arising from a relationship of trust and confidence be tween parties to a transaction") ( Powell, J., delivering the opinion of the Court). � j • 1 l 'l 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 201 The misappropriation theory, as employed by the Second C ir cuit, imposes liability whenever a trader uses information in breach of this duty of trust and confidence. It thus applies in situa tions where the trader owes no fiduciary duty to the source of the info rmation or to stockholders of the issuer of the security traded. The district court decision in United Sta tes u. Reed demon strates the degree to which this theory expands liability.90 The court held that the breach of a relationship of trust and confidence between family members was a sufficient basis for alleging fraud. The indictment in Reed charged the following facts: Gordon Reed, the father, was a director of a company that was the subject of merger negotiations. Gordon Reed told his son, Thomas , of the merger proposal before it was publicly announced. The son bought stock on the basis of the tip.91 The court found that, although the family relationship alone did not give rise to the necessary duty for 10b-5 liability, because the father had a long-standing pattern of confiding in his son, there was sufficient evidence of a duty92 to permit prosecution.9 3 Recently, the same court concluded that the relationship be tween psychiatrist and patient was also sufficient to give rise to 1 0b-5 liability. In United States u. Wi llis , 94 the district court held that the United States could prosecute a psychiatrist who breached his doctor-patient duty of confidentiality by trading on informa tion he received in the course of treating a patient,9 5 on the basis 90 601 F. Supp. 685 ( S . D . N . Y. ) , reu 'd i n p a r t on o t h e r grounds, 773 F.2d 477 (2d Cir. 1985). 9 1 Reed, 60 1 F . Supp. at 690-9 1 . 9 2 The court d i d not explain whether the confidential relationship gave rise to a duty to disclose ( presumably it did not) , a duty to abstain from trading, or some other kind of duty that made Reed's use of the i n formation improper. 93 Reed, 60 1 F . Supp. at 7 1 7 - 1 8 . Defendant Reed was ultimately tried before a j ury and acquitted. John C . Coffee, Jr., The 'Chest man ' Case: Misappropria t ion, Rule 1 -fe-3, 202 NY L.J. 5, 33 n . 1 7 ( 1 989) . 9' 737 F. Supp. 269 (S.D.N.Y. 1 990). 9 0 The psychiatrist learned through his treatment of Joan Weill that her h usband was attempting to become chief executive officer ( C EO ) of BankAmerica. The psychiatrist then purchased BankAmerica stock on the basis of this i n formation. !d. at 27 1 . It is not clear from the opinion that Sanford Weill's efforts to become CEO were generally con fidential. See Janet Bush, Psychiatrist who Tra ded on Pa tien t 's A nx ie t ies, THE FINANCIAL TIMES, May 19, 1 990, at I 3 ( d iscussing psychiatrist's claim that h e was unsure information he traded on was confidential). According to the SEC complaint, however, Mrs. Weill also told Willis that her husband's plans for the company included making a significant capita! infu sion. See S E C v. Willis , Exchange A c t Release No. 1 2 ,754, 1 9 9 1 S E C LEXIS 1 5 2 , at * 2 (.Jan. 202 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 26: 1 7 9 that this breach supplied the necessary element for insider trading.9 6 The misappropriation theory raises more questions about the scope and source of the underlying duty than the classical theory. At the forefront is the relationship between the wrongful conduct and securities fraud. As alluded to earlier, the questions about whether the fraud in an insider trading case is in connection with a securities transaction are exacerbated when the victim of the mis appropriation is not a m arket participant. This difficulty is appar ent in United Sta tes u. Carpenter.97 Foster Winans, a columnist for the Wa l l Street Journa l, and his tippees were prosecuted for trading on information that Winans had gathered for use in a Journa l column, "Heard on the Street," containing stock market recommendations. 98 The columns in which the information would appear had been prepared and publication dates set, but the issues containing the columns had not been published at the time the defendants traded. 99 The defendants were convicted of insider trading on the theory that Winans misappropriated property of the Journal by using information about the upcoming columns as a basis for trading. 100 Although Winans had clearly violated a Journa l rule prohibiting prepublication trading by employees, there was no indication that this violation injured investors . 1 0 1 Nonetheless, the S econd C ircuit 1 4 , 1991 ) . Subsequent t o Willis's purchase, B a nkAmerica publicly announced that W eill h a d sought to become CEO and that BankAmerica was not i nterested i n his offer. BankAmerica stock traded at prices somewhat higher than i n the five weeks preced ing the announcement. Dr. Willis then sold his stock for a profit of approximately $27 ,476. Willis , 737 F . Supp. at 2 7 1 ; S E C v . Willis, 777 F. Supp. 1 1 65, 1 1 68-69 (S.D.N.Y. 1 99 1 ) . 9 6 Willis , 737 F . Supp. a t 274-75. D r . Willis pleaded guilty t o the criminal charges against him and settled a civil injunction action by the SEC by agreeing to d isgorge h is trading profits and pay a civil penalty. Doctor Guilty in Insider Case, N Y. TIMES, June 29, 1 990, at 0 1 5: SEC v . Willis, Exchange Act Release No. 1 2 ,7 5 4 , 1991 SEC LEXIS 1 5 2 , at *2 (Jan. 1 4 , 1 99 1 ) ; s e e a lso United States v . W i llis, 7 7 8 F . Supp. 205, 209 ( S . D . N . Y. 1 9 9 1 ) ( refusing t o dismiss indictment i n light of en bane decision in Ches t ma n ) . "7 791 F .2d 1024 ( 2d Cir. 1986 ) , aff'd b y a n e q u a lly divided Cou r t , 4 8 4 U.S. 1 9 ( 1 9 8 7 ) . 98 !d. at 1026. "" !d. at 1 027. ' "" !d. at 1025. The Wall Street Jou rn a l hf.ld a formal policy prohi biting prepu blication trading and making the contents of upcoming col umns the exclusive p roperty of the .Jo u r n a l . l d . at 1 026. '"' A direct injury to investors could b e d emonstrated i f Winans pu blished information that was false, i n tending to induce investors to trade, and thereby profiting from the market 1991] INSIDER TRADING 203 affirmed Winans's conviction for insider trading1 0 2 and , in doing so, failed to adhere to the Blue Chip requirement that, in order for liability to attach under Rule 10b-5, the defendant's fraud must result in a securities transaction by the victim . 10 3 Describing the lower courts ' findings , the Supreme Court explained, Although the victim of the fraud, the Journal, was not a buyer or seller of the stocks traded in or otherwise a mar ket participant, the fraud was nevertheless considered to be "in connection with" a purchase or sale of securities within the meaning of the statute and rule. The courts reasoned that the scheme's sole purpose was to buy and sell securities at a profit based on advance information of the column's contents. 1 04 The Supreme Court affirmed W inans's insider trading convic tions by an equally divided vote. The Supreme Court's opinion is not explicit, but it i s likely that the four Justices who voted to reverse in Carpenter were troubled by the issue of whether, under the misappropriation theory, there is a sufficient connection be tween the fraud and a purchase or sale of securities. 1 05 effect of t h e false information. 1 02 Carpenter, 79 1 F.2d at 1 033. Winans's conviction for securities fraud was atlirmed by an equally divided Supreme Court. The Supreme Court unanimously affirmed his ccmvic tions for wire and mail frauds. Carpenter v. United States, 484 U . S . 1 9 ( 1 987 ) . 1 03 The Second C i rcuit had previously established its position that B l u e Chip did not require l iability to be based on the breach of a d u ty to a purchaser or seller of securities. United States v . Newman, 664 F.2d 1 2 , 17 (2d Cir. 1 98 1 ) , cert. denied, 464 U.S. 863 ( 1 983 ) . T h e district court in Newman dismissed t h e indictment because Newman h a d n o t breached a d uty to, and thereby defrauded, any seller of securities. !d. at 14. The Second C ircuit reversed, finding that Rule 10b-5 does not require the defrauding of a buyer or seller of securities and holding that l i ability could be prem ised on Newman's breach of his duty to his employer. /d. at 1 7 . ' "' Carpenter, 484 U . S . at 2 4 . T h e Second C ircuit h a d previously used similar reasoning to find a connection with t h e purchase or sale of securities in its development of the m isap propriation theory. For example, i n Newman, the court concluded that "since appellee's sole purpose in participating in the misappropriation of confidential takeover information was to purchase shares of the target companies, we find l i t tl e merit i n h is d isavowal of a connection between the fraud and the purchase." 664 F.2d a t 1 8 . 1 05 Inde<:: d , under t h e B l u e Chip doctrine, see supra notes 65-68 and accompanying text, the Journ a l , the victim of the fraud, would lack standing to bring a private civil claim against Vv inans for securities fraud because i t was not a purchaser or seller. Barbara B. A ldave, Th e Misapprop ria t ion Theory: C arpenter and its Aft er m a t h , 4 9 O H I O ST. L..J. 873. 376-77 ( 1 988 ) ; Nicholas Georgakopoulos, Note, Classical and Cross Insider Trc.ding Varia tions on t h e Th eme of R u le I Ob - 5 , 2 8 AM. B us. L . J 109, 136 ( 1 990 ) . N o r i:. the S e ccmd . 204 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE VI [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 Although i t may b e wrong t o violate a relationship of trust and confidence by breaching an employer confidentiality policy, as W i nans did i n Carpenter,106 o r b y using information obtained in the course of rendering psychiatric services, as in Wi l lis , 1 07 these wrongs are not fraudulent or deceptive. It is difficult to understand how trading on information obtained through such a relationship defrauds 108 the source of the information or anyone else. 1 09 If Dr. Willis trades on confidences obtained from his patients or discloses them at a cocktail party, he has done harm to the trust that his patients have reposed in him. The disclosure, however, while it vio lates the psychiatrist-patient privilege, does not constitute fraud . Unlike the Cady, Ro berts duty to disclose or abstain, the acquirer's duty to the source under the misappropriation theory is one of simple nondisclosure . The source is harmed if its confidences are disclosed, regardless of whether the acquirer subsequently trades, and the harm is not exacerbated by his trading. It is important to recall, in this context, that section l O ( b ) is triggered only by deception. We do not think of the doctrine of common -law fraud as applicable to a son who makes use of infor mation received from his father in a relationship of trust and confi dence, even if by using the information the son is breaching that trust. 1 10 Once again, we must reconcile the notion of what consti tutes a fraud under section l O ( b ) with the Supreme C ourt's re minder that this section was aimed only at fraud, as well as the C i rcuit's statement regarding the p urpose of the fraud satisfactory. Accordi n g to the court's reasoning, any theft or fraud would constitute securities fraud as long as the defendant i ntended to use the proceeds of the crime to p urchase stock. Carpenter, 7 9 1 F . 2d at 1 0 3 1 . 1 0 6 Com mentators have argued that the Journal suffered damage to its reputation. See, e.g. , Macey, supra note 44, at 43 ( " I f readers thought that the Journal's fi n a ncial news was tainted by its reporters' quest for personal profit, the paper's influence, and therefore its readership and advertising revenues, would decl i n e . " ) . 1 07 U ni ted States v. Willis, 737 F . Supp. 269, 275 (S.D.N.Y. 1 990). 1 0 8 In general, in order for the government to obtain a conviction on the basis of fraud, it must prove that the defendant contemplated some harm or injury to his victim. See, e.g U n i ted States v . S tarr, 8 1 6 F.2d 94, 9 8 ( 2 d C i r. 1 987) ( reversing mail fraud convic:tions be cause government fai led to prove that defendants intended to harm customers). 1 0 9 The court in Willis explained that " [b ) y not advising his patient of his i ntention to disclose her confidential i n formation and to profit personally from it, D r . W i l lis fraudulently induced his patient to confide i n him i n connection with his purchase and sale o f securities . " Wi l lis, 7 3 7 F . Supp. at 274. 1 1 0 See supra notes 90-93 and accompanying text (discussing U n i t e d States v . Reed, 601 F . Supp. 685 ( S . D . N. Y . ) reu 'd in part on o t h er grou nds, 77:3 F . 2 d 4 7 7 ( 2d Cir. 1 98 5 ) ) . . . 19 9 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 205 c ave at that even Rule lOb-5 does not provide a remedy for all fraud. 1 1 1 I t i s hard t o see how any breach o f a private duty o f nondisclo sure can implicate the objectives of the securities laws , which are concerned with duties to the market. Protection of the securities markets and innocent investors does not seem to bear any relation to whether an employee breached a duty of confidentiality to his emp loyer, or a son to his father . 1 1 2 Is it any different to a third party trading contemporaneously in the market if W inans traded with permission of the Jou rna l, if Reed lacked any sort of relation ship of trust and confidence with his father, or if confidential infor mation was overheard by a third party who had no duty whatso ever to the source of the information? 1 1 3 Finally, it i s not clear that expansion o f insider trading under the misappropriation theory is necessary. There are alternative ways to address much of the conduct to which the theory has been applied. One of the thorniest areas in the insider trading debate is the extent to which the prohibition should cover trading by outsid ers. In particular, classic outsiders, such as Winans , do not obtain their information as corporate insiders or tippees. Thus, prosecu tion of such outsiders requires doctrine to be stretched very thin. It might be preferable to remove these cases from the insider trad ing area altogether. After all, Winans was not trading on classic " inside" information; the information that formed the basis of his ' " S e e supra text accompanying note 68 (discussing B l u e Chip d ecision ) . 112 I n United States v. Newman, t h e Second C i r c u i t expressly cautioned t h a t t h e indict ment was based on a breach by the defendants of a duty to their employer and the em p loyer's cli ents, not on a duty to the marketplace or to the shareholders of the target com panies. 664 F.2d 1 2 , 15 n . 1 (2d Cir. 1 98 1 ) , cert. denied, 464 U.S. 863 ( 1 983 ) . The Second C ircuit subsequently explained, in Moss v. Morgan Stanley Inc., that the breach of a duty to the source under the misappropriation theory cannot b e " stretched to encompass an em p loyee's 'duty of d isclosure' to the general public." 7 19 F.2d 5 , 1 3 (2d Cir. 1 983), cert. de nied, 465 U.S. 1 025 ( 1 984 ) . But see Norman S . Poser, Misuse of Confide n t i a l Information Concerning a Tender Offer as Securities Frau d , 49 B ROOK L. REv. 1 265, 1 270 ( 1 983) ("Re gardless of how the defendant received the i n formation . . . public i nvestors are equally i n need of protection . " ) . 113 An exampl e of this last scenario is provided by SEC v. Switzer, 590 F. Supp. 756, 766 ( W . D . Okla. 1984), i n which the SEC attempted to prosecute a football coach who traded based on d iscussions he overheard while in the stands at a game. The court rejected the SEC's argument since Switzer was not i n a fiduciary position and did not know the informa tion on which he traded was the result of an insider breach. !d. 206 GEOR GIA LA W R E VIE W [Vol. 26: 1 79 columns was all in the public domain . 1 14 Winans conceivably might have been prosecuted for " scalping," a legal theory that does not depend on an insider trading analy sis. 1 1 5 Scalping is trading by an investment advisor for his own ac count based on the market effect of his recommendations to inves tors . 1 1 6 Although scalping is p rohibited by the Investment Advisors Act of 1940,1 17 these prohibitions probably do not apply to newspa per reporters. 1 18 Alternatively, prepublication trading may be viewed as traditional securities fraud. 1 1 9 One might treat a colum nist's recommendations as a representation to the public, upon which the column's readers rely in purchasing and selling securi ties. Clearly, when a financial columnist publishes a column of stock recommendations, he intends to convey information to the financial marketplace and expects readers to make trading deci sions in reliance on those recommendations. The columnist who makes prepublication trades in order to benefit from the publica tion effect of his column has a conflict of interest. 120 The purchases ' ' ' S e e Brudney , supra note 1 3 , a t 368- 7 1 ( d iscussing liability for trad i n g o n i n formation within public domain). " ' S e e SEC v. Capital Gains Research B ureau, Inc. , 375 U . S . 1 80 , 181 ( 1 963) (holding scalping to be fraud or deceit upon client or prospective client). " " !d. at 1 96. Although a n i nvestment advisor may readily anticipate the market effect of a good faith recommendation, the danger i n scalping is that an advisor will recommend a given security not because of i ts potential for a long-term price i ncrease but because of its potential for a short-term price reaction to the advisor's recommendation. 117 15 U.S.C. §§ 80b - 1 to 80b - 2 1 ( 1 988). " " The definition of investment advisor under the 1 940 Act explicitly excludes " th e pub l isher of any bona fide n e wspaper, n ews m agazine or business or fi nancial p ublication of general and regular circulation." 15 U.S.C. § 80b-2 ( a) ( l l ) ( 1 988) . The statute does not ad dress the status of reporters or employees of a publisher. See Cox, supra note 5, a t 385 ( p lacing Winans and the Journal beyond reach of I n vestm e n t Advisors Act) . 119 See, e.g. , Zweig v. H e arst Corp. , 594 F.2d 1 2 6 1 , 1 2 7 1 ( 9th Cir. 1 97 9 ) . I n Zweig, the court found that a newspaper columnist who made a practice of engaging i n p r e pu blication trading could be civilly liable under Rule 10b-5 for failing to d isclose the conflict o f i nterest i nherent in his trading. See a lso SEC v. C ampbell, [ 1 972- 1 97 3 Transfer B i nder] Fed. Sec. L . R e p . ( C C H ) 11 93,580, at 92,703 ( C . D . Cal. 1972) ( reporting prosecution of i n vestment colum n ist under Rule 10b-5 for prepubli cation trading) . 120 As the Ninth C ircuit stated in Zweig, " [R ] easonable i nvestors who read the colu m n would have considered t h e motivations of a fi n a ncial columnist such as Campbell i mportant i n deciding whether to invest i n the companies touted." Zweig, 594 F.2d a t 1 266; see Cha sins v . Smith, B arney & Co., 438 F.2d 1 167, 1 172 ( 2d Cir. 1 970) (requiring broker/dealer to d isclose fact that i t was a market maker i n recommended stock); see a is o B rudney, supra n ote 1 3 , at 369 (arguing that columnist makes implied warranty of disinterestedn ess, which i s breached by scalping); Cox, supra note 5, at 385 (arguing that client is a ided i n assessing strength of analyst's recommendation by knowledge that analyst "is serving two masters, 1 991 ] INSIDER TRADING 207 will increase in value, based on the columnists favorable recom mendation, whether or not the stock is actually worth more than the current market price. Thus, it seems that Winans could be prosecuted for failure to disclose his own trading to the paper's re aders /2 1 who are then defrauded in connection with their subse quent sale or purchase in relia:qce on the column. 1 22 Similarly, misappropriation theory covers a range of wrongful conduct that can be addressed with standard criminal laws / 2 3 such as theft and mail fraud. 124 The burglar who breaks into an office in order to obtain confidential corporate information for trading is stealing as well as engaging in insider trading. 125 Moreover, the theft of corporate information through less dramatic means may qualify as conversion or embezzlement. 126 Many of the proposed definitions of insider trading would only exacerbate this problem. With their emphasis on the wrongful ac quisition of inside inform ation, the proposals would increase the one o f which is his own self- i nterest"). 11 1 One commentator suggests that the alternative is to have the newspaper publish a statement disclosing that employees are permitted to engage in prepublication trading. Mar tin Kimel, Note, The Inadequa cy of R u le l Ob-5 to Address Ou tsider Trading by Reporters, 38 STAN. L. REv. 1549, 1 5 7 1 ( 1986 ) . 1 22 The theories whereby scholars claim Winans's scheme damaged the reputation of the Journ a l are based o n the belief that the Jou rnal's readers will perceive the content o f the columns as tainted by Winans's personal p rofit motive and accord them less reliability. See supra note 1 06. 123 M isappropriation theory has also been criticized on the basis that it duplicates state agency law. Georgakopoulos, s upra note 105, at 137 n.93. 1 24 In Chiarella , Chief Justice B urger q uoted with approval a passage from a 1 936 law review article that stated , " [a ] ny time information is acquired by an i l l egal act it would seem that there should be a duty to disclose that i n formation. " C hiarella v . U nited States, 445 U.S. 222, 240 ( 1 980) ( B urger, C.J., dissenting) (quoting W . Page Keeton, Fra u d � Concealment and Non-Disclos u re , 15 TEx. L. REv. 1, 25-26 ( 1936 ) ) . The mere fact that the acquisition has taken place through an illegal act suggests, however, that an alter native mechanism exists for redressing the wrong. See U nited States v. Carpenter, 791 F.2d 1024, 1036-37 (2d Cir. 1 986) ( M iner, J., d issenting i n part) ( arguing that broadening federal securities laws to cover Winans's conduct is unnecessary because conduct could be c:de quately addressed by mail and wire fraud statutes) , aff'd, 484 U.S. 19 ( 1 987 ) . ' 2 5 See, e.g. , S E C v . Cherif, 933 F . 2d 403, 4 1 7 ( 7 t h Cir. 1 99 1 ) (convicting under m isappro priation theory terminated bank employee who gained access to bank after d ischarge) , cert. denied, No. 9 1 -605, 1 992 U.S. LEXIS 658 (U.S. Jan. 27, 1 992). See genera lly Gary Lawson, The Ethics of Insider Trading, 1 1 H ARV. J.L. & PuB. PoL'Y 727, 767 ( 1 988) (stati ng that it is unclear why state criminal law is n ot adequate for insider trad ing that is equivalent of theft ) . ' 2 " See, e.g. , Macey, supra n ote 4 4 , at 28-29 (arguing that Chiarella's u s e of tender offer information for his personal trad ing was breach of contract and theft ) . GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 208 [Vol. 26: 1 7 9 duplication between insider trading and current criminal statutes. For example, the SEC's proposed insider trading bill would pro hibit the use of, among other things, information that has been obtained by or as a result of " theft, bribery, misappropriation or espionage. " 1 27 The proposed Insider Trading Proscriptions Act of 1 9 87128 would prohibit the use of information obtained by " theft, conversion, [or] misappropriation. " 1 29 II. APPLICATI ONS OF C URRENT IN SIDER TRADI N G LAW Notwithstanding the logical flaws , many commentators accept the judicially developed theories of insider trading, based on a fun damental perception that insider trading is unfair a n d wrong. 1 30 Given this perception, one might conclude that those who engage in such trading should be held liable in spite of the diffi culties in articulating the rationale for such liability. Even with this ap proach, however, the problems associated with insider trading reg ulation are evident. The viability of a theory of liability does not depend only on whether liability is reasonable but also o n whether it can be imposed in a logical manner. A. LIABILITY FOR TIPPING One fundamental difficulty is determining how to impose liabil ity for tipping. Who, if anyone , should be prosecuted when an in sider, rather than trading himself, tips the information to others who trade in reliance on that information? Under both the classi cal and the misappropriation theories o f insider trading liability, the original acquirer of the information and anyone who receives the information from that acquirer may be held liable for insider trading . Indeed, in Cady, Ro bert s , the defendant who traded on the basis of inside information was not a corporate insider but the 1 2 7 Securities and Exchange Commission Proposed I nsider Trading B i l l ( Nov. 1 8 , 1 98 7 ) [ hereinafter SEC Modified Proposal ] , repri n t e d i n SEC Compro m is e Prop o s a l o n Insider Tra ding Legis l a t i o n ; Accompa nying L e t t e r, and A n a lysis by A d Hoc Legis l a t ion Com m i t Sec. Reg. & L . R e p . ( B N A ) No. 4 7 , at 1 8 1 7 ( Nov. 2 7 , 1 9 8 7 ) . T h e b i l l is also reprinted in Symposium, D e fi n i ng "Insider Tra ding ", 39 ALA. L. REv 531 app. ( 1 988 ) . 128 S . 1 3 80, lOOth Cong., l s t Sess. ( 1 987 ) , repri n t e d i n Symposium, s u p ra n o t e 1 2 7 , at 53.5 app. 1 2" !d. § 3 : s e c K im e l , supra note 1 2 1 , at 1 564 ("Federal securities laws are n o t needed t o protect employers from theft. " ) . "'0 E.g , B rudney, s u p ra note 1:3 , at 3.54 - 5 5 ; B a i nbridge, s u pra n o t e 2 2 , a t .J .J - (3 2 . tee, 19 1 99 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 209 partner of a director. The Commission failed to explain how the tippee inherited his p artner's fiduciary duty; it simply based liabil ity on the fact that the broker knew the information was nonpublic and had been received from an insider. 1 3 1 The courts appear t o predicate the liability o f a tippee o n the tipp er's breach of some duty. As the C ourt in Chiare l la explained, " [t] he tippee's obligation [ not to profit from the inside informa tion] has been viewed as arising from his role as a p articipant after the fact in the insider's breach of a fiduciary duty. " 1 32 Thus, it is necessary for the tipper to act wrongfully in order for his tippee to incur liability. The extent of this requirement was clarified in Dirks u. SEC, 133 in which the Supreme Court found that Secrist, the corporate insider and source of the information/ 34 had com mitted no breach of fiduciary duty in disclosing the information to a securities analyst, Dirks. 1 35 Accordingly, Dirks could not have been a participant after the fact in a breach of fiduciary duty and hence could have no derivative liability as a tippee . 1 36 The SEC has taken the position that a tippee stands in the shoes of the tipper, inheriting the tipper's fiduciary duty. If the tipper would be barred from trading by virtue of his insider position, the tippee is similarly barred. 137 The Court in Dirks , however, rejected this position . 1 38 The C ourt held that, before a court imposes liabil ity upon a tippee, the government must satisfy a two- part test. In addition to proving a primary breach of fiduciary duty by the tip1 3 1 In re Cady, Roberts & Co., 40 S . E . C . 907, 9 1 2 - 1 3 n . 17 ( 1 96 1 ) . Chiarella v . U n i ted States, 445 U . S . 222, 230 n . 1 2 ( 1 980) . 1 33 463 U.S. 646 ( 1983). "' Secrist, a former officer of Equity Funding of America (EF A), disclosed to Dirks, a securities analyst, that a major fraud was being perpetrated at EFA. Secrist " u rged D irks to verify the fraud and d isclose it publicly." !d. at 649. 1 36 ld. at 666. The Court's m e thod of determining whether Secrist breached a fiduciary duty in revealing the fraud to D irks may have been overly simpl istic. The Court concluded that the test for whether a n i nsider acted improperly in revealing inside i n formation was " w hether the i nsider personally w i l l benefit, directly or i ndirectly, from his disclosure. " ld. at 662. Thus, an i nsider breaches h is duty i n revealing i nside information only i f he receives a personal benefit from the d isclosure, such as a pecuniary gain or a benefit to his reputa tion that will translate i n to future earnings. !d. S ince Secrist received no money or personal benefit, the Court held h e had breached no duty to EFA. !d. at 662. 1 36 !d. at 667 . The Court concluded that t ippees do not inherit the i nsider's duty to dis close or abstain merely because they receive i nside i n formation; tipees only i nherit the in sider's duty i f the i n formation " has been made ava i lable to them imp.-operly . " !d. at 660. 1 3 7 !d. at 655. 13" !d. at 655-59. 1 32 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 210 [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 per, the government must show that the tippee knew o r h a d reason to know that the information was nonpublic and had been wrong fully obtained . 1 39 Neither requirement fills the void in the Cady, Roberts opinion. The Court in Dirks still did not explain how a tippee who does not obtain (or pass on) inside information-in breach of a fiduciary duty to the stockholders, the source of the information, or someone else-can commit securities fraud by trading on the basis of that information. How can such trading be a fraudulent omission if the tippee has no duty to speak? 140 Agency principles do not supply an answer. Even if the original insider had a fiduciary duty to his shareholders, the tippee does not inherit that same d uty upon re ceiving a tip. Moreover, if the insider tips in breach of a duty of nondisclosure, it is illogical to find that this duty of nondisc losure is converted , in the hands of the tippee, into a duty to dis c lose. The problem is further complicated by the willingness of Con gress 1 4 1 and the courts to impose insider trading liability upon an insider who tips but does not trade. 1 42 Such liability is really sec ondary in nature; the insider is aiding and abetting the violation committed by the tippee's trading. But if the insider abstains from trading, he is not violating the Cady, Ro berts duty. Moreover, un less disclosure of the inside information harms the company (or 1 "" 1 10 ! d . at 6 6 1 -64. It has been suggested that a tippee " in h erits" the duty from the tipper as long as the tippee knew or should have known that the i n formation was improperly obta in e d . SEC v . M usella, 578 F. Supp. 425, 439 (S.D.N.Y. 1 9 8 4 ) ; see Phill ips & Zutz, supra note 5, at 89 ( terming this the " ' inheritance' theory . " ) ; cf. D irk s , 463 U . S . at 655-56 ( rejecting notion that tippee i nherits Cady, Roberts duty absent breach of that duty by tipper). 14 1 The Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1 984, § 2, 1 5 U .S . C . § 78u ( d ) ( 2 ) ( 1988) , provides for the imposition of civil penalties o n nontrading tippers based on the belief that " [ a ] bsent the tipper's misconduct. the tippee's trading would not occur." H . R. REP. No. 355, 98th Cong., 1 st Sess. 9, reprin ted in 1 983 U . S . C . C.A.N. 2274, 2282. 1 '" See, e.g. , Shapiro v . Merrill Lynch, P ierce, Fenner & Smith, Inc., 495 F.2d 228, 241 (2d Cir. 1 974) ( holding stockbroker l iable for tipping institutional clients based on i n formation M errill Lynch received as result of p erforming u nderwriting work ) ; see a lso S E C v. Texas Gulf Sulphur C o . , 401 F . 2 d 833, 848 (2d Cir. 1 968) (describing duty of insider who possesses material nonpublic i n formation to " abstain from trading i n or recommending the securities concerned while such inside i n formation remains u n disclosed") ( emphasis added ) , cert. de n ied, 394 U.S. 976 ( 1 969 ) . Indeed, Dirks d i d not himself trade i n the stock of E q uity Fund i ng. Dirks, 463 U.S. at 665. T hese cases can be addressed , as the D istrict o f Columbia Cir cuit did in Dirks, by finding that securities professionals, by virtue of their position, have a fiduciary duty to the marketplace not to e ngage in selective d isclosure. D i r ks v. SEC, 681 F.2d 824, 840 ( D . C . C i r. 1982), reu'd, 463 U.S. 646 ( 1 983 ) ; s e e infra note 265. 1 99 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 211 res ults i n personal gain t o the insider ) , it is difficult to find a brea ch of fiduciary duty, even when the disclosure is selective . 143 Thus, the courts impose liability for a tipper's breach of a duty of nondisclosure alone. But this breach is no more deceptive if a tip pee purchases securities based on the information disclosed than if the tippee sells the information to a competitor or otherwise uses the information to his business advantage. This contradiction is the result of focusing on the tipper's fiduciary obligations to assess whether the insider trading prohibitions have been violated. Whether the tippee trades is irrelevant. Nevertheless, the SEC does not appear to have taken the position that disclosure by cor porate insiders of inside information is, by itself, insider trading or securities fraud, as long as no subsequent recipient of the informa tion trades securities in reliance on the information. B. CHO O S IN G BETWEEN CLASSICAL THE ORY AND MISAPPROPRIATION A major difficulty in applying the existing insider trading theo ries is choosing which theory to use. Courts have not always distin guished clearly between the two theories144 in reviewing insider trading convictions. 1 411 Nor is it always intuitively obvious which theory is appropriate . For example, professionals such as invest ment bankers and lawyers are frequent targets in insider trading prosecutions based on their misuse of information conveyed to them for professional purposes. Such traders can be prosecuted " 3 An example is a recently settled action by the SEC against Phillip Stevens, the former CEO of U ltrasystems Corp . , SEC v. Stevens, 91 Civ. 1 869 ( C S H ) ( S . D . N . Y . Mar. 1 9 , 1 9 9 1 ) . See Ex- CEO Sett les Charges H e Disclosed A dverse Inside Information t o A n a lysts, 23 Sec. Reg. & L. Rep. (BNA) No. 12, at 439 ( M ar. 22, 1 99 1 ) [herein a fter Ex- C E O ] . Stevens alleg edly conveyed nonpublic i n formation to securities analysts that Ultrasystems would have lower earnings than expected. The SEC claimed that Stevens tipped in order to i mprove "his status as a corporate manager . " Id. A pparently Stevens believed tipping would enhance his cred ibility among analysts and enable h i m to function as a more effective CEO. Thus, S tevens's tips can be viewed as attempts to help the issuer rather than as a breach of his fiduciary duties. 1 44 Some commentators believe that derivative or tippee liability should b e treated as a d istinct category of i nsider trading regulation. E.g. , LANGEVOORT, supra note 2, at 1 0 1 -39. This belief is based, i n part, on the fact that derivative liability brings additional analytical problems to the i nsider trad i ng debate. See id. at 363-94 ( noting gray areas of i nsider trad ing liability ) . ' " When used t o refer t o insider trading l itigation, t h e term " couviction" should b e read broadly to include cases in which the government has been successful in a civil enforcement a ction or admi nistrative proceeding as well as a criminal prosecution. 212 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26 : 1 79 under the classical theory based on the view that they became tem porary insiders when they received information for a corporate purpose. 145 Alternatively, under the misappropriation theory, the traders may be prosecuted as outsiders who have m isappropriated the information through the process of converting it to their per sonal use. Professionals also may be viewed as tippees, although, after Dirks, such a predicate for liability appears dubious because corporate officers do not breach a fiduciary duty in communicating information to professionals for business purposes. The problem is illustrated by the recent prosecution of Robert Chestman. 1 47 Chestman, a broker, was prosecuted under the mis appropriation theory for trading on information about a forthcom ing tender offer for the stock of Waldbaum, Inc. C hestman ob tained the information from Keith Loeb, a nephew by marriage of a Waldbaum insider. 148 Loeb had no inside position in the com pany, and he disclosed the information to Chestman voluntarily; between Loeb and Chestman there was no theft or breach of confi1 16 The Court stated in Dirks: Under certain circumstances, such as where corporate information i s revealed legitimately to an underwriter, accountant, lawyer or consultant working for the corporation, these outsiders m ay become fiduci aries of the shareholders. The basis for recognizing this fi duciary duty is not simply that such p e rsons acquired nonpublic corporate i n formation, but rather that they have e n tered into a special confidential relationship i n the conduct of the business o f the enterprise and are given access to i n formation solely for corporate p u r poses. D i r k s v . SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 655 n . 14 ( 1983 ) . When such a person breaches h is fi d uciary relationshi p , h e may be treated m o r e properly as a tipper than as a tippee. Thus, for exam p l e , in SEC v. Musella, 578 F . S u p p . 425, 441 ( S . D . N . Y . 1 984), i n which the office manager of a law firm disclosed i nform ation about the merger and acquisition plans of the firm's clients, l iability m ight more appropri ately have been based on the treatment of the d e fendant as a constructive insider. Instead, the court d e termined that the defendant had, i n tipping, m isappropriated the i n formation. I d . a t 43839. 1 1 7 United S tates v . C hestman, 903 F.2d 75, 82, 84 ( 2d Cir. 1 990) , v a c a t e d in part on reh 'g, 947 F.2d 551 (2d Cir. 1 9 9 1 ) (en bane) . The court's decision en bane reversed C hest man's conviction for insider trading under Rule lOb-5 but upheld his conviction under Rule 1 4e-:3, see i nfra note 1 50. 1 18 The government's theory of the case was that C hestman had received inside i n forma tion about Waldbaum stock from Loeb. !d. at 75. Chestman maintained that his trading was motivated by his independent analysis of Waldbaum stock. Chestman claimed that h e d i d not d i scuss Waldbaum stock w i t h L o e b p r i o r to m a k i n g the purchases f o r which he was p:·l•secuted. !d. at 555. C hestman's testimony at trial was cmroborated by t h a t of his admin istrati·,·e assistant, who testi.fied that as of late morning or early afternoon of the day C hestman purchased Waldbaum stock, Chestman had not spoken to Loeb. F l um enbaum & l'� a r p , suprn note 8, at 3. 1991 ] INSIDER TRADING 213 dence. Thus, Chestman could b e prosecuted only a s a tippee and, at that, only as a remote tippee. 1 49 The panel of the Second Circuit that heard Ches tman came to three separate conclusions with respect to Chestman 's conviction under Rule 14e-3150 but unanimously reversed Chestman 's convic tion under Rule l Ob - 5 . 1 5 1 Upon rehearing en bane, a sharply di vided Second C ircuit agreed with the panel and reversed the con viction under Rule lOb-5.152 The court held that prosecution under the misappropriation theory, under which C hestman was charged ,u':3 required proof that C hestman knew Loeb was breach ing a relationship of trust and confidence, that is, misappropriating information. 1 54 The evidence with respect to Loeb's misappropria tion was shaky at best-the information had been passed down a chain of fami ly members, in each case upon a pledge of secrecy that was broken. 1 55 Loeb received the information from his wife, who was not a Waldbaum insider, who had no fiduciary duties to the co�pany, and who was expressly authorized to disclose the in- ' '" Ch est m a n , 9 4 7 F . 2 d at 570- 7 1 ; s e e Coffee, supra note 9 3 , at 5 (''Put simply C hestman was a fourth-level tippee . " ) . "" S EC Rule 1 4 e - 3 , 1 7 C . F . R. § 240. 1 4e - 3 ( 199 1 ) , regulates trading whenever a bidder has either taken substantial steps to commence or has commenced a tender offer. Absent public disclosure, the rule prohibits trading by anyone who is i n possession of m aterial nonpublic information concerning the offer and who knows or has reason to know that the information came from the bidder or the target com pany, d i rectly or indi rectly. The bidder is exempted from this prohi bition. The Second Circuit panel reversed C hestman's conviction under Rule 14e-3 by a two-to one vote. Judge M ahoney felt that Rule 14e-3 was an invalid exercise of the S EC's rulemak ing power. Ches t m a n , 903 F.2d a t 84 ( M a honey, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part) Judge Carman determined that Rule 14e-3 required proof of fraudulent acts and de termined that, because the trial court did not instruct the j ury on the elements of fraud, Chestman's conviction must be reversed. !d. a t 86 (Carman, J . , concurring i n part) . The e n b a n e court, however, d isagreed w i t h t h e panel and concluded both that R u l e 14e-3 was a n appropriate exercise of the SEC's rulemaking power and that C hestrnan ' s convict ion under the rule was proper. Ches t m a n , 947 F.2d at 556-64. The validity of Rule 14e-3 obviously implicates a number of the issues discussed herein, but a comprehensive treatment of the rule is beyond the scope of this Article. 1 5 1 Ches t m a n , 903 F.2d at 80, 84, 86. '" 947 F.2d 551 (2d C ir. 199 1 ) (en bane ) . Five j udges dissented from the reversal of C hestma n 's convictions under 10b-5. !d. at 57 1 . ' ·' " C hestman was convi cted o f both aiding a n d abetting insider trading b y assisting Loeb's purchase of stock and of trading as a tippee with respect to purchases on behalf of h i mself and others. Chest m a n , 947 F.2d at 564. . • "' ' / d . ," See Ches t m a n , part l . 903 F.2d at 77; Ches t m a n , 947 F.2d at 579 ( \Vinter, , J . , dissenting in GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 214 [Vol. 26: 1 7 9 formation to her husband. 1 56 Moreover, there was n o evidence that Loeb ever agreed to keep the information confidential. 111 7 Under those circumstances, the court found it impossible to conclude that Loeb had breached a duty in disclosing the information to Chestman . 1 58 If there was no breach of duty, then C hestman, not withstanding the fact that his conduct suggested consciousness of guilt, 1 5 9 could not have knowledge of such a breach. At oral argument before the en bane court, the prosecution tried to base a duty on the family relationships involved, i n p articular on the marital relationship between Keith and Susan Loeb . The prosecution argued that the marital relationship was persuasive, if not conclusive , evidence of a relationship of trust and confi dence. 1 60 From this relationship , the government tried to infer a duty to hold interspousal communications confidential. 1 6 1 The dif ficulties with this approach are apparent. It would be difficult enough for the family member involved, much less his tippee, to evaluate every conversation with a relative and to distinguish relia bly confidential conversations from ordinary family gossip . 1 62 Of course, the government was not required to prosecute C hestman under the misappropriation theory. Intuitively, the classical theory of insider trading seems better suited to the facts of the Chestman case. Ira Waldbaum, the original source of the confidential information, was a traditional insider. 1 63 The informa tion was passed from Waldbaum to Chestman through a series of Waldbaum family members.164 Why is this not a classic case of re mote tippee liability? One answer is that the case illustrates the above-described logical difficulties with derivative liability for tip1 06 1 07 Chestman, 9 4 7 F.2d at 5 7 9 ( Winter, J . , dissenting i n part ) . !d. at 57 1 . " s I d. 1 06 !d. This conduct included his denial that h e had ever d iscussed the W aldbaum stock with Loeb. See id. at 555-56. 160 In his opinion, dissenting on the reversal of C hestman's convictions under Rule lOb-5, J udge W inter attempted to articulate a test for recog n izing a fiduciary duty b ased on a familial relationship. !d. at 579-80 ( W i nter, J . , dissenting in part ) . 161 !d. The Chestman indictment c h arged that Loeb had breached a d uty o f trust and confidence to his wife and her family when h e tipped C hestman. Chestman allegedly aided and abetted this breach by trading. C offee, supra note 93, at 5. 162 See C h e s t m a n , 947 F.2d at 582 - 83 ( M iner, J . , concurring) ( criticizing " familial rela tionship" rule as difficult to apply and i n h i biting family discourse ) . 16" I d. at 555. 1 6·1 Jd . j l ·l ! 1991] INSIDER TRADING 215 p ees. 1615 Ira Waldbaum disclosed the information t o Shirley Witkin , his sister, for valid business p ur p oses-Witkin had to assemble her stock certificates in order to effect the u p coming sale of the busi ness. 166 Since Waldbaum 's disclosure of the sale was for valid busi ness p ur p oses and not for im p ro p er p ersonal gain, it was not a breach of any fiduciary duty. Under the reasoning of Dirks, if Waldbaum breached no duty in disclosing the information, Witkin could not be liable as a ti pp ee for subsequent disclosure or trading.167 Accordingly, any culp able conduct in this case is limited to the disclosure of the transaction by Loeb to Chestman and the subse quent trading by Loeb and Chestman. B ut this conclusion brings us back to the question asked by the Ches tman court: why was the information confidential in the hands of Loeb? Is the sanctity of the marital relationshi p really the basis for the jury's determina tion that Chestman's conduct constituted insider trading? Should insider trading p rosecutions be a tool to enforce the maintenance of s p ousal confidences? If the concern of the securities laws is the p rotection of investors through com plete disclosure of investment information, why should Chestman 's liability for insider trading be de p endent u p on whether the Loebs' marriage constituted a rela tionshi p of trust and confidence? 168 1"' Professor Langevoort notes that tippee-derivative liability, especially based on tips to friends or relatives, constitutes one of the "gray areas" in insider tradi n g regulation. LANGEVOORT, supra note 2 , at 389-94. 166 Ches t m a n , 947 F.2d at 555. 1 67 I t can be argued that Witkin, too, was a n i nsider, s ince s h e owned Waldbaum's stock and was a party to the sale that Ira Waldbaum had negotiated. Assuming that Witkin was an i nsider, one m ust analyze her disclosure to determine i f i t was an i mproper tip. Witkin was Susan Loeb's mother, and when Susan Loeb became anxious that her mother's activities reflected a problem with her health, Witkin d isclosed the upcomi ng sale to ease her daugh ter's anxiety. Ches t m a n , 903 F.2d at 77. Witkin did not d isclose the sale for personal gain or to make her daughter a g i ft, so, under Dirks, Witkin's d isclosure was not a breach of any i nsider's duty. Chestman, 947 F.2d at 579 ( Winter, J . , dissenting in part). Moreover, Witkin told Susan Loeb she could tell her husband about the sale, so when S usan d isclosed the transaction to Keith she breached neither a duty as a tippee nor a relationship of trust and con fidence. !d. at 555. 1 68 The Third C ircuit's opinion i n Rothberg v. Rosenbloom, 7 7 1 F.2d 8 1 8 ( 3d Cir. 1985), provides an equally compelling i llustration of the problem of identifying the appropriate theory upon which to predicate i nsider tradi ng liability. Defendant Rosenbloom was an i n sider of Nytronics, a corporation engaged in an attempt to take over Culton I n d ustries. Rosenbloom tipped Rothberg as to both Nytronics's intention to take over C ulton and his expectancy that the attempt would be successful, based on Nytronics's favorable contacts on l l GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 216 [Vol. 2 6 : 1 79 j '1 j C. LIMITATIONS OF BOTH THEORIES The Ches t man case is not the only difficult factual s ituation under current lines of insider trading analysis. Consider the situa tion of a business acting as a maj or supplier to a corporation. The supplier is advised by the corporation's executives that the corpo ration has significant expansion plans, as yet unannounced, and ac cordingly will be substantially increasing its orders with the sup plier. If the supplier trades on that information, has i t engaged in insider trading? 1 69 The supplier is, in a sense, a tippee, but the information was communicated to the insider for business pur poses rather than securities trading. Arguably the supplier m ay be viewed as a temporary insider when it receives the tip , but it is unlikely that a supplier that only receives payment fro m the corpo ration for material provided can be viewed as owing a fiduciary duty to the corporation and its shareholders . 1 70 Nor can the sup plier be considered to have misappropriated the information, even if the executives describe the corporation's plans as confidentiaU71 t h e Gulton board. !d. at 8 2 1 -22. The Third C ircuit concluded that Rosenbloom's tip violated insider trading law under the m isappropriation theory because Rosenbloom "owed [ Nytronics] a duty not to d isclose se cret i n formation which would cause others to buy Gulton stock, thereby making i t more difficult for Nytronics to consummate a merger on favorable terms . " !d. a t 822. I n his con curring opinion, Judge H igginbotham agreed with the majority's conclusion but found i ts reliance on the m isappropriation theory to be misplaced. According to Judge H igginbotham, the significance of the tip was based on the disclosure of the Gulton board 's likely receptive ness to the offer, i n formation that came not from Nytronics, the acquirer, but as a leak from G ulton, the target. !d. at 825 ( H igginbotham, J., concurring) . Even under a fraud-on-the source theory, Rosen bloom d i d n o t owe a fiduciary duty to Gulton as source o f the i n forma tion. Judge H igginbotham concluded that Rosenbloom should instead b e fou n d to h ave vio lated i nsider trading law under the classical doctrine based on the fact that Dr. G ulton, the G ulton insider who had contact with Rosenbloom, breached a fiduciary d uty under the Dirks analysis i n leaking the i n formation. Id. (Higginbotham, J . , concurring) . 1 69 Professor Brudney would argue that the supplier has access to an i n formational ad vantage that is not available to the general p ublic and hence should b e barred from trading. See B rudney, supra note 1 3 , a t 359 ( arguing that supplier/customer s ituation i n vokes dis close-or-refrain rule) . 170 I d. at 359 ( [ N ] o legal doctrine seals a supplier's knowledge of a significant i ncrease in orders by a customer. " ) . 171 O n e commentator refers to situations i n w h i c h insidErs, b y virtue of their position, receive knowledge about other corporations, to which they owe no fiduciary d uty, as " cross trading. " G eorgakopou!os, supra note 105, pass i m . The author suggests that, although cross trading is not classical i nsider trading, it can be reached under the m isappropriation theory. Further, according to the author, i t s hould b e reached because the policy considerations for banning cross- trading are even stronger than those underlying the general regulation of in" I 1 991 ] INSIDER TRADING 217 The corporation cannot unilaterally impose restrictions o n infor mati on the supplier has legitimately obtained. 172 Those who argue that trading by the supplier in this case does not present the same dangers of manipulation of corporate events and harm to the corporation as trading by insiders may consider the converse factual scenario, in which the supplier decides to cut off the supply of material to the corporation and , in anticipation of that decision, sells the corporation's stock short.173 Should insider trading regulation be expanded to cover someone who acts in breach of a contractual duty to the corporation , such as that im posed by a supply contract, and trades " in connection with" that breach? 1 74 Finally, consider a corporation that deems itself a possible take over target. Management, fearing a hostile takeover attempt, ap proaches other companies as prospective white knights, seeking to enter into :1 merger on friendly terms . m; Although the disclosure of sider trading. Id. at 1 33 . 1 72 T h e corporation could, w i t h t h e consent o f t h e supplier, restrict t h e supplier's right to use the i nformation by contract. This possibi lity raises the question of whether the sup plier's breach of that contract could b e bootstrapped into an insider trading violation like that i n the Carpenter case. 173 Professors Carlton and Fischel d escribe the situation of a short seller as providing the same moral hazard as that of an insider. D ennis W. Carlton & Daniel R . F ischel, The Regu lation of Insider Trading, 35 STAN. L. REv. 857, 874 ( 1983) . 1 7 4 Professors Carlton and Fischel suggest that there i s n o real possibility o f i nsider trad ing prosecution i n this situation. !d. The supplier, however , m ight logically be indicted under the m isappropriation theory, based on the claim that he had a contractual duty not to use information derived from his business relationship for his personal gain, or under the classical theory, based on the argument that h e has become a temporary insider of the sup plied firm. See infra note 175 ( discussing situations i n volving temporary insiders ) . 1 7 6 This factual scenario is similar to those i n a n umber o f reported cases. For example, in SEC v. Ingram, [ 1 987-88 Transfer B i nder] Fed. Sec. L . Rep. (CCH) 11 93,788, a t 98,720 (C.D. Cal. 1 988) , Ingram, a securities analyst, wa�' asked by the corporation to look for a merger partner. I ngram, who was not compensated for his services. located a partner and sat in on the merger negotiations. During the course of the negot iations, he tipped several of his bro kerage clients about the deal. The court h e ld that Ingram, by virtue of his participation i n t h e d e a l , h a d become a temporary insider w h o inherited a Cady, Roberts duty. ! d . Earlier, in SEC v. Lund, 570 F. Supp. 1 397, 1 399-400 ( C . D . Cal. 1 98 3 ) , a corporate insider asked Lund i f he was interested i n participating i n a lucrative joint venture with the corporation. Lund declined to join in the deal but purchased stock in the corporation, realizing a $ 1 2,500 profit. The d istrict court found that Lund was guilty of insider trading, holding that the i nsider's approach to Lund made him a temporary i nsider of the corporation and imposed upon him the obligation to keep the i n formation confidential. !d. at 1403. B u t see Walton v. Morgan Stanley & Co. , 623 F.2d 796, 799 ( 2d Cir. 1 980) ( holding that fi nancial advisor of acquiring entity has no duty to target entity even when target disclosed confidential infor- GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 218 [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 confidential corporate information about the issuer i s , in these sit uations , generally subj ect to an appropriate confidentiality agree ment that prevents the white knight from trading on the basis of the information obtained, there is nothing to prevent a prospective white knight from rej ecting the suitor's advances and purchasing target stock based on the knowledge that the target is seeking an acquirer or " shopping the company. " 176 These initial contacts may precede public disclosure by the corporation that it is a target.1 7 7 III. THE BASIS FOR THE INSIDER TRADING P R O H IBITION The foregoing analysis of the Ches tman decision demonstrates the gap that has developed between the regulation of insider trad ing and the traditional goals of the securities laws. It also calls into question what should be done to regulate insider trading regula tion. Development of the existing case law has been logically incon sistent and possibly unfair, a result that is hardly surprising in the absence of any clear statutory or common-law prohibition. Com mentators have observed that the law is sorely i n need of clarifica tion; many have called for a clear definition of the prohibited con duct.178 This outcry requires some reflection on the basic rationale for prohibiting insider trading. 179 If there is no clearly defined pro hibition, why have the courts and the SEC decided that insider trading is i llegal? Are they correct? In other words , having deter mined that section 10(b) does not provide an appropriate basis for prosecuting misuse of inside information, we are left to question mation to advisor for express p urpose of exploring acquisition deal with d i fferent acquiring entity). 1 76 Whether the firm's trading violated SEC Rule 14e-3 would b e a separate issue. See supra note 1 50 ( discussing Rule 1 4 e - 3 ) . 177 I n the initial stages a corporation is typically shopped through a n i nvestment banker without d isclosure of its identity to avoid this kind of trading. Many i n the i ndustry believe that i f those approached can ascertain the identity of the company being shopped, they are free to trade. 1 78 See supra note 5. m In considering the purposes of regulating insider trading, this A rticle will not consider the general objectives behind the antifraud provisions. Those objectives h ave been described as including the p rotection of public investors against overreaching by issuers, the enhanced market efficiency that results from i ncreased disclosure of relevant corporate i n formation, and the regulatory function ascribed by J ustice Brandeis to disclosure as a d i rect deterrent to fraud. See Lours BRANDErs. OTHER PEOPLE's MoNEY AND How THE BANKERS UsE I T 62-63 ( 1933) . For a general d iscussion of the functions of the antifraud p rovision and c itation to the relevant legislative history, see B rudney, supra note 13, at 334-36. · INSIDER TRADING 1 99 1 ] 219 whether such a prohibition is desirable and, i f so, what form it should take. A. ECONOMICS, FAIRNES S , AND PROPERTY RIGHTS: POPULAR RATIONALES F OR REGULATION Scholars have debated at great length whether insider trading sh ould be regulated. Although an extensive analysis of this debate is beyo nd the scope of this Article, the battle lines are commonly drawn between those commentators who believe that insider trad ing increases the efficient operation of the markets and those who view insider trading as harmful to the markets, the firms whose sec urities are traded, or both. Professor Henry Manne has been gen erally credited1 80 with focusing the insider trading debate by rejecting criticisms of insider trading in terms of fairness and in stead basing the analysi s on the perceived costs181 and benefits 182 1 80 HENRY G. MANNE, INSIDER TRADING AND THE STOCK MARKET v i i - v i i i ( 1 966) ; R a y A . Schotland, Unsafe a t A ny Price: A Reply t o Manne, Insider Trading and the Stock Market, 53 VA. L. R E v 1425 ( 1 967); Henry G. Manne, Insider Trading a n d t h e Law Professors, 2 3 VAND. L. REv. 547 ( 1 970) ; see, e.g. , Carlton & Fischel, supra note 1 7 3 , a t 8 5 7 n . l (citing Manne's book as " starting point" for subject) : Carney, supra note 7 1 , a t 863 n.2 (citing Manne's book as " seminal"); Langevoort, supra note 26, a t 1 n . 1 ( citing M an ne 's book as initial source for article). 1"1 It has been suggested that insider trading causes a decl i n e i n i nvestor confidence and ultimately a decrease i n the flow of money to the capital markets. As the Supreme Court has observed, " [w ] ho would knowingly roll the dice in a crooked crap game? " B asic, Inc. v. Levinson, 485 U.S. 2 24, 247 ( 1 988) (citation omitted) . Moreover, one of the congressional purposes in adopting the federal secur ities laws was to restore i nvestor confidence in the securities markets. See, e.g. , In re Faberge, Inc., 45 S.E.C. 249, 254 ( 1 973) ("One of [the Exchange Act's] p rimary objectives was to restore and maintain i nvestor confidence in the capital markets of the United S tates. " ) ; see a lso Securities Exchange Act of 1 934, § 2 , 1 5 U.S.C. § 78b ( 1 988) (explaining " [n ] ecessi ty for regulation " ) ; cf. Spencer Cerek, Note, In sider Trading, SEC Decision-lvfa k i ng, a n d t h e Calculus of Inuestor Confidence, 16 HoFSTRA L. REv. 665, 675 ( 1988) (arguing that SEC's emphasis on high-profile i nsider trading prose cutions may do more harm than good with respect to investor confidence ) . In addition, t h e ability t o engage i n insider trad ing m a y create perverse incentives for corporate management, encouraging management to manipulate corporate decisions in order to create trading opportunities and to delay reporting of operations to accommodate trading by insiders. The former problem is commonly described as " moral hazard." See, e.g. , Saul Levmore, Securit ies a n d Secrets: insider Tra ding a n d t h e Law of Contracts, 68 VA. L. REv. 1 1 7, 149 ( 1982) ( arguing that insiders can structure corporate transactions i n order to profit from a decrease in corporate stock prices ) ; Schotlan d , supra note 1 80 , at 1 4 5 1 (discussing belief that insider's trad ing i n shares may i mpede insider's commitment to corporation 's business ) ; ,Joel Seligman , The Re,form u la t ion of Federal Securit ies Law Concerning Non pu b lic Inform a t i o n , 73 GEO LJ. 1 083, 1095 ( 1 98.5) ( d iscussing inside trader's ability to ma nipulate release of news, adopt riskier practices t o detriment of shareholders, and profit by . 220 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 26: 1 79 of such trading. This analysis, while interesting on a theoretical level, has not generated any clear consensus, probably because of the absence of empirical data. 183 Unless the effect of the legaliza tion of insider trading on investor confidence or management be havior can be quantified, it is impossible to determine whether such effects justify retaining the existing prohibition. 184 Alternatively, the debate can be returned to the issue of fairness. A common view of insider trading is that it is unfair to other trad ers. Insiders possess an informational advantage by virtue of their p osition or through fortuity and should not reap a windfall by us ing that information for personal gain. 1 85 Whether other traders bad as well as good events ) ; Anabtawi, Note, supra note 5 , at 386 ( arguing that where moni toring b y shareholders i s costly and shareholder and management i nterests are not the same, managers may fail to maximize shareholder wealth ) . Section 1 6 (c) of the Exchange Act, which prohibits short sales by corporate insiders, has been cited as a congressional attempt to deal with the moral hazard problem. E.g . , The!, supra note 1 9 , at 476. For a discussion of the possibility that insiders may delay d isclosure to enhance their personal trading, see Bainbridge, supra note 22, at 50- 5 1 ; Cox, supra note 39, at 636-37; Robert J . Haft, The Effect of Insider Trading R ules o n t h e Internal Efficiency of the Large Corpora tion, 80 MICH. L. REv. 1 05 1 , 1 053-60 ( 1 982 ) ; Kenneth E . Scott, Insider Trading: Rule J Ob-5, Disclosure and Corpora t e Pri!J·acy, 9 J . LEGAL STUD. 80 1 , 8 1 0- 1 8 ( 1980). '"" Free-market advocates claim that insider trading i ncreases the use of i nformation i n the markets and thus causes stock prices t o become more accurate. Several commentators have made the argument that insider trading is a form of executive compensation and, be cause of the type of trading opportunities created, may lead to desirable management be havior. E.g . , Carlton & Fischel, supra note 173, 870; Ronald A . Dye, Insider Trading a nd Incen tives, 57 J. Bus. 295, 298-308 ( 1 984) ( providing formal econometric analysis) . ' 8 3 See, e.g. , B a inbridge, supra note 22, at 63-65. ' "' See Easterbrook, Stlpra note 37, a t 338 ( arguing that questions of whether i nsider trading restrictions are j ustified are ultimately empirical) . ' " 6 M a n y also believe that insider trading d irectly hurts conte mporaneous traders in the market by causing them to trade at an improper time or p rice. See, e.g. , W illiam K.S. Wang, Trading on Impersonal Stock Ma rkets: Who is Harmed, and Who Can Sue Who m Under SEC R u l e l Ob-5, .54 S. CAL. L . REv. 1 2 1 7 ( 1981 ) . P rofessor Wang has argued that i nsider trading may have the effect of inducing others to trade or preempting the trades of other i nvestors. Id. at 1 235-36. He explai ns that all trading i n securities is subject to the " law of conservation of secu r i ties," under which the profits gained by an insider m ust be directly offset by lo8ses sustained by other investors. Id. at 1 235. Professor Wang concludes that, i f insiders profi t , other investors m u s t b e harmed, although i t may b e difficult to determine who those investors are. !d. at 1 236-38. But see Bainbridge, supra note 22, a t 42-45 (arguing that i nsider tnJ d i ng causes securities to be p riced more accurately i n situations in which corporation is permi tted to w ithhold material information) ; Easterbrook, su pra nute 37, a t 3 2 4 - 2 7 ( arguing that insider trading is unlikely to result in unfair transactions for other traders) ; G i lson & Kraakman, supra note 1 1 , at 6:30-34 (arguing that insider t r ad i ng is u n l ikely t o have any effect on market p r i c e u nless p rivate information is e ffectively transmit ted to mar k e t ) . 1 99 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 221 are harmed directly, such as b y inducement to trade at an incor rect price , or indirectly, through the presence in the market of other traders who possess an overwhelming informational advan tage, inequality of information is at the heart of the fairness ra tio n ale. Yet, few suggest that insider trading be regulated by a par ity - of-information standard.186 Instead, the unfairness associated with insider trading has been attributed to inequality of access to information. 187 As Professor B rudney explains, the unfairness asso ciated with the insider's use of corporate information is based on the fact that the insider has a "lawful monopoly on access to the inform ation involved . . . which cannot be competed away. " 1 8 8 Apart from insiders who gain access to information by theft or its equivalent, when does the insider's access to information make his trading activity unfair ? 1 89 Obviously, participants in the market 1 86 At least one commentator has suggested that Congress enact a parity -of-information approach by statute. Seligman, supra note 1 8 1 , a t 1 1 37 -40. 1 87 The Supreme Court has expressly rejected the theory that all traders are entitled to equal information. See D irks v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 657 ( 1 983) ("Judge Wright correctly read our opinion i n Chiarella as repudiating any notion that all traders must enjoy equal infor mation before trading: ' [T ] he "information" theory is rejected . ' " ) (quoting Dirks v. SEC, 681 F.2d 824, 837 (D.C. Cir. 1 98 2 ) , r e u 'd, 463 U . S . 646 ( 1983 ) ) . Although many argue that the level-playing-field theory i s addressed not t o equal i nfor mation but to equal access, the Court in Chiarella also rejected unequal access to informa tion as a basis for imposing liability. Chiarella v . United States, 445 U . S . 222, 235 n . 20 ( 1980 ) . Even the Second C ircuit, with its expansive view of i nsider trading, does not take the position that the regulation of insider trading is designed to equalize access to i n fo r m a tion. "We do not say that merely using information not available or a ccessible to others gives rise to a violation of Rule 1 0b-5 . . . . There are d isparities in knowledge a nd t h e auailability thereof at many levels of market functioning that the law does not presume to address." U n i ted S tates v. Carpenter, 791 F.2d 1 02 4 , 1 0 3 1 (2d Cir. 1 986) ( em p hasis added ) . 188 Brudney, s upra note 1 3 , at 346. 18 9 It is unclear why disparate access to information and the exploitation of that ;c, c c e s s present a unique problem in the securities indus try. Business transactions are routinely predicated on the fact that one party to the transaction has superior information of which it intends to take advantage. An obvious example is the series of real estate purchases that gave rise to the i nsider trading opportunity in the Texas G u lf Sulphur case. SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 4 0 1 F.2d 833, 844 (2d Cir. 1 968) (en bane) , cert . denied, 394 U . S . 976 ( 1969 ) . Texas Gulf Sulphur was buying land because of its superior knowledge that there were extraord inary mineral deposits in that land, without revealing its d iscovery to t h e sell ers. Id . Although the purchases may have been unfair to the sellers, they surely wen; not fraudulent. Indeed, the Ontario H igh Court of Justice, i n a case arising out of the s c: m e factual situation as that l itigated before the Second Circuit, found that Texas Gulf Su lphur had done what any prudent m ining company would do i n pursuing the purchases w i t h o u t disclosing the d iscovery. Leitch Gold M ines, Ltd. v. Texas Gulf Sulphur C o . , 1 O . H . 4 6 9 . 492-93 ( 1 969 ) . For a further discussion, see Anthony Kronman, Mis t a k e , Disclosure. Infor ma tion, a n d t h e Law of Contra c t s , 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 20- 2 1 ( 1 978). 222 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 2 6 : 1 7 9 do not possess equivalent information. For example, the average analyst or other market professional has a great deal more infor mation about the stocks he trades than the average small investor. Although this inequality may be unfair/9 0 it is not seriously sug gested that analysts be precluded from taking advantage of this informational asymmetry. 191 M arket professionals expend a great deal of effort trying to obtain information that does not duplicate what everyone else has, 192 through discussions with corporate in1 90 E v e n advocates of the e q u a l access theory of regulation accep t t h a t there is " system atic inequality of lawful access to i n formation by reason of disparities among i n d ividual investors with respect to power, wealth, d iligence, or i n telligence." B rudney , supra note 1 3 , a t 360. I t has been suggested that the u n fairness o f a llowing investment analysts t o trade on and sell superior i n formation i s addressed by the fact that, while every i nvestor cannot be come a corporate insider or the confidante of such an insider, everyone can obtain the ser vices of an i n vestment analyst. Donald C . Langevoort, Inves t m e n t A n a lysts and the Law of Insider Trading, 76 VA. L . REv. 1 02 3 , 1 0 3 2 ( 1 990) . Therefore, all i n v estors do have access to analyst i n formation. This argument overlooks two factors. F i rst, even among the customers of an i n vestment analyst, there i s asymmetrical access to i n formation. Many analysts selectively allocate the i n formation they obtai n , auctioning valuable i n formation off to t h e h ighest bidder, or dis closing the most significant i n formation only in oral conversations with favored clients. The i n formation received by the typical investor, such as i n the form of the fi r m 's newslette r , i s often markedly i n ferior. ! d . a t 1 039. I n d e e d , i n the Dirks case, i t was D irks's allocation o f h i s information t o his large institutional clients a t t h e expense o f smaller i nvestors t h a t t h e D istrict of Columbia Circuit found t o b e u n fair. Dirks v. S E C , 6 8 1 F . 2d 8 2 4 , 84 1 ( D . C . C i r . 1 98 2 ) , rev 'd, 4 6 3 U . S . 6 4 6 ( 1 983). Second, the customers of an investment analyst pay for the i n formation they obtain. While an analyst is not an absolute free rider, i t is unclear why h e s hould b e compensated for the information acquired. That is, why h as the analyst acquired some sort of property r ight in the i n formation by virtue of the tip? Even if the analyst system achieves market efficiency, why is i t socially preferable to allowing corporate insiders to sell i n formation di rectly to the public? 19 1 A naiysts may garner personal advantage from trading for their p roprietary accounts, from bonuses and other compensation schemes that reward superior i nformation, and from benefit to their reputations. Moreover, because superior i n formation generates greater busi ness and the market for financial services is highly competitive, an a nalyst who has access to inside information furthers his career substantially. See Langevoort, sttpra note 1 90 , at 1 042-43. 1 " 2 The average small investor is a u tomatically a t a d isadvantage due to his inabil ity to follow the market and its developments on a full-time basis. C harles C . Cox & K evin S. Fogarty, Bases of Insider Trading, 49 O H I O ST. L.J. 353, 360 n.23 ( 1 988 ) . Some scholars, such as Professor Brudney, would not b e concerned with this d is parity , arguing that the relevant d istinction is not equality of i n formation but equality of access and that as long as any investor may, through expending sufficient resources, obtain the e q uivalent information, the investment professional's i n formational advantage is not unfair. B rudney, supra note 1 3 , a t 322. This argument begs t h e question: Should t h e inquiry focus o n actual access o r theo retical access ? See Easterbrook, supra note 37, at 330 ( pointing out that access to i n forma tion is fu nction of cost of obtaining i n formation and that inequality of access is thus natural 19 9 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 223 siders , following the progress of important litigation , or monitoring news reports and the Dow Jones tape constantly. 1 9 3 Should the arbitrageur who keeps close watch on an important lawsuit be pre cluded from trading as soon as the court announces its ruling be cause he has an informational advantage over the rest of the in vesting public? 1 94 If not, how can legal informational advantages be distinguished from those that form an impermissible basis for trading? 1 9 5 The method employed by existing legal theory is to brand as impermis sible those informational advantages acquired through the breach of a fiduciary duty. Yet, for the investor-victim, it is irrelevant whether the trader has acquired inside information through the breach of a duty or not; anyone who trades based on superior in formation not available to the investing public has obtained a trad ing advantage that is arguably unfair . 1 96 Moreover, as previously result of unequal d istribution of i ntelligence, wealth, and investment of human capital). 1 9 3 Indeed, arbitrageurs go much further, attempting to ferret out i n formation directly from corporate insiders. A n arbitrageur's assessment of an investment opportunity may be based en factors that include not merely what an insider says, but also his " tone of voice, . . . the way a question was answered or avoided, or . . . the fact that a telephone call was not returned . " Sarah Bartlett, Business a n d Law: Cases Illustrate Wa li S t . 's Edge, NY TIMES, Aug. 28, 1 989, at D2. 1 9 ' As Professor B rudney observes, the search for relevant corporate and economic infor mation is a service of value to the functioning of the capital markets. The search entails research costs that will not be allocated for that purpose unless the i nvestor is able to re ceive the rewards of the i n formational benefits so obtained. Brudney, supra note 1 3 , at 341 . On the other hand, it is possible that the selective favorable treatment of the fi nancial com munity leads to excessive research and competition for superior information. 1 96 This question assumes that all informational asymmetry is not unfair. Although the Supreme Court has rejected the level - playing-field underpinning for insider trading regula tion and has refused to uphold l iability in the absence of a breach of duty, see supra note 187, Congress could choose to impose such a standard. 1 96 An example of trading that appears i mproper but i nvolves no breach of a fiduciary duty is pre-offer trading by a prospective tender o fferm. When an individual who is about to make a tender offer for the stock of a target company purchases stock p rior to announcing the tender offer, h e is, in some sense, trading on inside i n formation about the forthcoming announcement, but since the bidder owns the i nformation , the trading is legal. See C hiarella v. Un ited States, 445 U.S. 222, 2 ::l 1 -32 n . 14 ( 1 980) ("The Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit previously held, in a manner consistent with our analysis here, that a tender offeror does not violate § l O ( b ) when it makes preannouncement purchases precisely because there is no relationship between the offeror and the seller . . . . ") (citing General Time Corp. v. Talley Indus., 403 F.2d 1 59, 164 (2d Cir. 1968 ) , cert. denied. 393 U.S. 1 026 ( 1 969 ) ) . Yet, if the bidder tells a friend about the offer, which, as owner of the information, he should be entitl ed to do, and the friend proceeds to trade in the t arget company's stock, the friend's trad ing violates Rule 1 4e-3. See supra note 1 50 (discussi ng Rule l 4 e -::l ) . 2 24 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 26: 1 7 9 discussed, neither the insider 's fiduciary duty to the firm nor the misappropriator 's duty to the source forms a logical and consistent justification for prohibiting trading. Most importantly, in this re gard, applying the Court's rules regarding fiduciary duty requires reference to the parties' private agreement. For example, if the Wa ll Stre e t Journa l had not had a rule maintaining the confiden tiality of its columns, \Vinans would not have breached a fiduciary duty by trading on the information contained in those columns. Similarly, if a corporation, through charter amendment, stock holder vote , or the equivalent, authorized its management to trade on the basis of inside information, there would be no breach of management's duty to stockholders upon which to predicate classi cal insider trading liability.19 7 This analysis has led some commentators to view insider trading in terms of property rights . 1 98 If corporate information is consid ered the property of the firm, then the conversion of the property for the insider's personal use is a theft. 1 99 Under this theory, an insider or misappropriator is a thief, and his tippee is receiving stolen property. 2 00 The property rights theory provides a justifica tion for prosecuting W inans for stealing information about upcom ing columns from his employer, even though the Wa l l Stree t Jour nal would have been free to trade on the information in question. 2 0 1 1 9 7 Although i t is rarely argued t h a t corporations should be able t o authorize insider trad ing d i rectly by treating corporate i n formation as property and contractually bargaining with management about the allocation of rights i n that property, some com mentators assert that corporations would be able to authorize such trading indirectly by relieving management of a fiduciary obligation not to trade. E.g. , Nicholas Wolfson, Trade Secrets a n d Secret Trad ing, 25 SAN DIEGO L. REv. 95, 1 1 3 ( 1 988). ' 98 S e e . e.g . , Carlton & Fischel, supra note 1 73, a t 86 1 ; Easterbroo k , s upra note 3 7 , a t 3:3 1 ; Edmund W. K i tch, The Law a n d Economics o f Righ ts i n Va luable Informa tion, 9 J . LEGAL STUD. 683, 7 1 8 - 1 9 ( 1980 ) ; Lawson, supra note 1 25 , at 7 59 ; Macey, supra note 44, at 9; Rich ard J . Morgan, Insider Tra ding a n d t h e Infringement of Property R ig h t s , 48 O H IO ST. L.J. 79 ( 1 987 ) . 1 9 9 Additionally, u s e of t h e i n formation by the insider m a y impair the corporation's abi l i t y t o exploit it further. T h e corporate owner may require that confidentiality be maintained i n order to profit fully. See, e.g. , SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 401 F.2d 833 ( 2d Cir. 1 968) ( fi nd ing that corporation mainta i ned confidentiality of drilling results i n order to confirm results and acquire land ) , cert. denied, 394 U.S. 976 ( 1 969 ) . '0 " Lawson, supra note 1 25, a t 767 ( " M r . Levine was thus a garden - variety thief, and M r . Boesky, w h o traded on the information and s p l i t t h e profits w i t h Mr. L e v i n e , was a fence . " ) . ' " 1 According t o t h e defendants in Carpenter, this anomaly meant t h e i r trading couid not violate the law. The court responded by explaining that, while the .Jo u rn a l m ight lawfully l l j ·i 1 l 1 99 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 225 The property rights approach also offers a method for dealing with two of the examples posed earlier: that of the corporate sup plier and that of the prospective white knight. 202 While neither has unilaterally created the inside information in the sense that would give rise to an unequivocal ownership i:1terest, both are trading on th e basis of information voluntarily imparted by a third p arty for the purpose of business dealings. The third p arty has the opportu nity to preclude trading on the basis of those dealings by contract, thereby restricting property rights in the information. Absent such a contractual provision, there is no misuse or theft in trading on the information. A more troubling aspect of treating inside information as prop erty is that such treatment does not j ustify government interven tion to allocate the property rights to information. If inside infor mation is the property of the firm producing it, why is it different from any other firm property, which the firm may allocate, as it chooses, by contract?203 This view would enable a firm to authorize its officers or employees to trade on the basis of inside information. The firm would, in effect, be opting out of the government enforce ment of its property rights. 204 In other words, viewing inside infor mation as property justifies treating the misappropriation of that undermine i ts reputation by trading on the basis of its knowledge of forthcoming publica tions, " its employees should be and are barred from destroying their employer's informa tional property." United States v. Carpenter, 791 F.2d 1 024, 1 033 (2d Cir. 1 986). ' " " S e e supra text accompanying notes 169- 1 7 7 . 203 T h i s argument is detailed i n t h e seminal article by Professors Carlton a n d Fischel. They argue that insider trading would b e regulated more efficiently i f firms were free to authorize insiders to trade. Carlton & F ischel, s upra note 173, pass i m . Professor Fischel and Judge Easterbrook have observed that p r ivate contract theory may not achieve optimal allo cation of the property rights i n i n formation due to a variety of factors, including the diffi culty i n enforcing contracts that restrict insider trading because of the practical problems of detecting improper trades. Frank H. Easterbrook, Insider Trading as a n Agency Problem, in PRINCIPALS A N D A GENTS THE STRUCTURE OF BusiNESS 8 1 , 90-97 (John W . P ratt & Richard J. Zeckhauser eds . , 1 985) [ hereinafter Easterbrook, Agency Proble m ] ; Easterbrook, s upra note 37, at 332-35; Frank H. Easterbrook & David R. Fischel, Trading on Inside Informa tion, 36 LAw ScH. REc. 10, 14 ( 1 990) . Although these observations m a y explain why firms have n o t chosen t o regulate i nsider trading by private contract, they do not j ustify a government ban on such contracts. " Public enforcement of antitheft laws does not imply that consensual transfers of property ought to be forbidden; j ust so with inside trading rules." !d. at 1 4 . 20 1 Addi tionally, t h e fi r m would be able to sell the i n formation t o others. S e e Jonathan R . Macey, From Ju dicial Solutions to Political Sol u t ions: The New, New Directions o f t h e R u les Aga inst Insider Trading, 39 ALA. L. REv. 3 5 5 , 376 ( 1 988). GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 226 [Vol. 2 6 : 1 7 9 property as theft but correspondingly requires the government to defer to firm decisions contractually allocating the entitlement to that property.205 If the wrong associated with insider trading is a harm to the is suer or to the source, as suggested by the classical and misappro priation theories, respectively, the harm m ight b e addressed through a regulation that protects property rights i n information but allows firms to bargain away those rights voluntarily, restrict ing the government's i nvolvement to enforcement of the privately negotiated bargain.206 B ut perhaps existing theories o f insider trad ing misapprehend the significance of insider trading. Is the ration ale for the public perception that insider trading i s wrong actually based on a perception that corporate insiders damage the i ssuer when they trade? This perspective seems unlikely. It is more plau sible that the public views insider trading as damaging to traders and to the trading markets. The insider , by virtue of his p osition, has obtained an unfair informational advantage over o ther tra ders. Thus, the traditional views of insider trading distort the doctrine by ignoring the concepts of market duty and market harm. B. JUSTIFYING REGULATION ON THE BASIS OF AN I N S I D E R ' S D UTY TO THE MARKET It might be argued that the C ourt in Chiare lla rej e cted a general duty of disclosure to the market and that such a d uty, therefore, ' " 5 According t o Coase's theorem , i n the absence of substantial transaction costs , p roperty rights will be transferred to t hose who can exploit them most p ro fitably. See genera lly David D. Haddock & Jonathan R. Macey, A Coasian Model of Insider Trading, 80 Nw. U L REv. 1 449 ( 1 987 ) (concluding, based on Coasian analysis, that ordinary s hareholders would be better off i f firms were allowed to opt out of proscriptions of current insider trad ing law ) . The SEC has not taken the position that i n formational rights can be transferred as property. For example, SEC Rule 14e-3 is i n consistent with the p roperty rights approach because it prohibits a b idder from consensually transferring i ts p roperty rights i n informa tion about a prospective tender offer to t h ird parties. See, e.g. , 17 C . F . R . § 240. 1 4e - 3 ( 1 99 1 ) ; Morgan , supra note 198, a t 1 1 3 (arguing that, under a property rights approach , bidder should be free to do whatever h e wants with such information, including giving it to others ) . 20" This approach would address the concern that private e n forcement is too d i fficult and costly to be effective i n banning insider trading, even where such trad i n g is inefli cient. See Easterbrook, Agency Pro ble m , supra note 203, at 94-95 ( arguing that, if fi rm cannot meet costs of establishing program to prohibit i nsider trad ing and o f detecting i m p roper trades, it is unl ikely to adopt private prohi bition, even where prohibition is socially beneficia l ) . See genera l ly supra note 203. INSIDER TRADING 19 9 1 ] 227 cannot be the basis for imposing insider trading liability. 20 7 There are two responses to this argument. First, the Court in Ch iare lla r eje cte d the concept that everyone, corporate insider or not, has a gen eral duty to the market.208 The Court, however, did not con sid er the specific question of whether a corporate insider such as an offi cer or director, by virtue of his position, has a duty to the tra ding market not to misuse nonpublic information. Sec ond, the Chiarella decision represents an interpretation of fi duci ary duties under the existing statutory language of section 10(b) . 209 As demonstrated earlier, section l O (b) is a poor statutory choice for regulating insider trading. 210 I f regulation is to be ef fected by a new statute, however, the limitations of Chiare lla need not apply. l'vloreover, if we are engaged in a search for an appropri ate statutory definition, i t seems appropriate to tie that definition to the rationale for regulation. Finally, imposing a market duty upon insiders is consistent with the overall structure and objectives of the federal securities laws, which are aimed primarily at the pro tection of investors and the capital markets , not at the protection of such fiduciary relationships as the physician-patient relationship. 2 1 1 Accordingly, a revised statutory approach to insider trading reg ulation can be predicated on the theory that a corporate insider has a duty to the marketplace not to misuse nonpublic informa tion . Why is the insider's use of non public information unfair? The answer can be explained, in part, by the importance of the capital markets to the large publicly held corporation. Absent a system in which corporations have ready access to capital markets, access which is facilitated by the availability of safe, liquid , regulated markets for secondary trading, the public corporation would be un likely to attain the same size and dominance. This growth , in turn, provides management with unparalleled opportunities for wealth and status. Thus, in a sense, the corporate insider's superior ac cess, due to his position , may be partially attributed to government and public participation in the markets. It is the fact that an in- ""' See Chiarella v. United States, 445 U.S. 222, 2 3 1 , 233 ( 1 980) ( rej ecting duty o f C h i ar e l l a " to the m a r k e t a s a whole " ) . too Jd . "0" 210 "11 See id. at 2 3 2 - 35 (premising h o l d i n g on l a nguage of section 1 0 ( b ) ) . See s u pra Part II. See U n i t e d States v. W i l l i s , 737 F . S u p p . 269, 272 ( S . D . N . Y 1 990). 2 28 GEOR G IA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 sider has obtained his i nformational advantage because of his posi tion, and the fact that this position is attributable to the presenc e of other less-privileged transactors in the market, that makes the insider's use of nonpublic information unfair. This conclusion does not necessarily imply that other market transactors are hurt by in sider trading.2 1 2 A POLITICAL EXPLANATION FOR RE GULATI ON O F INSIDER TRADI N G C. Before considering the new proposal, it is necessary to consider one additional factor: why the status quo prohibits insider trading. The preceding analysis suggests that the proffered j ustifications for regulating insider trading, particularly under the e xisting statutory scheme, are unconvincing. Yet in spite of the logical i nconsisten cies, insider trading enforcement continues as a high priority, and the SEC continues to expand its enforcement efforts with more ag gressive prosecutions and calls for stiffer sentences. The expansion of liability under section l O (b) is particularly surprising in view of the fact that the objectives of existing insider trading theory could be achieved more precisely by strengthening state law doctrines of fiduciary duty,213 coupled with the existing federal prohibition on short swing trading and short sales by corporate insiders.2 1 .1 B efore attempting to address the deficiencies in the existing regulatory scheme , it is important to understand the reasons for its evolution. This question can be answered, in part, by looking to who benefits from insider trading regulation. This Article contends that at least three major interest groups are beneficiaries of the existing regulatory scheme. One of these �12 B u t cf. supra note 1 8 5 ( c i t i n g partici pants i n d e b at e over w h e t h e r i n s i d e trad i n g harms o t h e r marke t transactor s ) . 213 M any commen tators, of course, v i e w state law as a n unsatisfactory m e t h o d o f d i s c i p l i n i ng corporate i n s i ders because of general i nstitutional fa i l ures s u c h a s the i n e ffective n ess o f the derivative s u i t and other tools for e nforcement o f state- law fiduciary d u t i e s . See, e.g. , .J i l l E. Fisch, Fra nkens t e i n 's Monster Hits the Campaign Tra il. An Approach to Regu la tion of Corpora t e Political Expendi t u res, 32 W :vt & MARY L. REv. 5 8 7 , 638 n n . 26 1 -63 ( 1 99 1 ) ( c i t i n g articles w h i c h assert that vot i n g a n d derivative s u i ts d o n o t p r o v i d e s u ffi c i e n t s hare holder control or m a n agerial accoun t a b i i i ty) . I n a d d i t i o n , t h e w i l l i ng n es s o f state legislatures and courts to decrease protection o f shareholders in the i n terest o f attracting corporate fr anc hises, the so- called race to the bottom, suggests that states w i l l b e slow to expand fi d u c i ary principles to l i m i t i n s i d e r trad i n g activity. See id. a t 635 n n . 246-47 (arguing that state l e g i s la t u res are influenced b y reve n u es of corporate fra nchise ta x ) . ·n • S e e su pra note 1 9 . 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 229 groups is the securities analysts. S ecurities analysts earn their live lihood by analyzing publicly available information215 and attempt ing to determine when a particular security represents a good in vestment. Because they have the time and expertise to acquire superior information, analysts are at an informational advantage ove r many members of the investing public.216 Moreover, under ex isting insider trading law, securities analysts enj oy a position of distinct legal advantage over the general public.217 After Dirks, dis clos ure by corporate insiders to analysts for reasons other than personal gain2 1 8 will be treated as lawful.219 This means that ana lysts enjoy a unique position in the market-regular access to ma terial nonpublic information220 without restrictions on its use.221 210 P u blicly avai l able information i s used i n its broadest sense in describing the work of secur i ties analysts. Frequently, analysts have access to sources of information that are not available to the general public. See supra notes 1 90 - 1 94 ( discussing disparity of information among market participants ) ; see a lso B rudney, supra note 1 3 , at 365 ( questioning whether analyst who makes overt i nq u i ries to firm's executives about future of company has received nonpublic information). " 6 Indeed, some commentators have described such market professionals as " quas i -insid ers ' ' due to thei r persistent advantage over all other traders. E.g. , Macey, s upra note 204, at 377. 217 See Langevoort, supra note 190, at 1 024 (concluding that investment analysts receive special treatment because of their perceived role i n increasing market efficiency ) ; Macey, supra note 204, a t 377 (stating that market professionals who are perm itted, even en couraged, to trade on basis of their lawfully acquired informational advantage benefit from general proscription on insider trading). 2 1 " Langevoort, supra note 1 90, at 1023-24. As Professor Langevoort observes, there are many reasons why an issuer m ight find i t desirable to d isclose i nformation through an ana lyst rather than a press release o r SEC filing. See id. at 1028-31 (citing four reasons for preferring d isclosure through analysts: ability to release substance without specifics, avoid ing liability , overcom ing moral hazard, providing i ncentive to analysts ) . " ' " Cf. S E C v. Stevens, 9 1 C i v . 1 869 ( C S H ) ( S . D . N . Y . M a r . 1 9 , 1 99 1 ) ; Ex - CEO, s upra note 143, at 439. I n S t e uens, an ex-CEO settled insider trading charges based o n selective tipping to securities analysts. The SEC charged that the CEO tipped i n order to enhance h i s profes sional reputation and his future earnings power as CEO. !d. """ Many scholars have attempted to justify d isclosure of nonpublic info r mation to ana lysts as in the best interests of the corporations. Among the arguments proffered are the clai ms that such d i sclosure is faster, more credible, l ess expensive, and more accurate than disclosure to the general public would be. E.g. , Daniel R. Fischel , Insider Trading and In L>es l m e n t A n a lysts: A n Econ o m ic A n a lysis of D i r ks v. Securities and Exchange Commission, 1 3 H oFSTRA L. Rzv. 1 27 , 1 40-42 ( 1 984 ) ; Helen Garten, Insider Trading in the Corpora t e Int eres t , 1 987 W i s . L. REv. 573, 625. This Article does n o t take t h e position t h a t selective d isclosure is j ustified. See, e.g . , Langevoort, s upra note 1 90 , at 1023 ( arguing " special treat ment" given to investment analysts under existing insider tradi ng l aw i s excessive and un viarranted ) . Moreover, the SEC has indicated that it does not accept the notion that the !Ji,- b· d e c i s i .J n gives corporate insiders carte blanche to make selective d isclosure to ana- I 230 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 In an ideal world, the information provided by investment ana lysts would be useless. P erfectly efficient markets would cause in formational changes to be reflected immediately in stock prices, with the result that an analyst could not, on the basis of public information, provide advice that would produce a better-than -av erage return.222 The continued use of i nvestment analysts can be justified only by the conclusion that, under the current regulatory scheme, analysts are able to provide superior information.223 Ana lysts' ability to provide this information might be explained as proof that the markets are not perfectly efficient.224 In the alterna- lysts. SEC Commissioner Edward H . Fleischman, P resentation to University of California 1 3th Annual Securities Regulation Institute (Jan. 24, 1 9 9 1 ) [ hereinafter Fleischman, Presen tation ] . Regulation requiring corporations to handle d isclosure through a n eutral method such as press releases would address this u n fairness. 22 1 The special treatment of the analyst has been justified by the important role that analysts play i n market efficiency. Congress explicitly stated that the Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1 988, Pub. L. No. 1 00-704, 102 Stat. 4677 ( codified in scattered subsections of 15 U.S.C. § 7 8 (Supp. 1 988 ) ) , was not intended to cut back on the deference to analyst tipping recognized by Dirks: [The Dirks test was meant] to ensure that the insider trading laws do not in hibit honest communication between corporate officials and securities analysts. The Committee recognizes that market analysts play a crucial role i n facilitat ing the d issemination of information to the marketplace, and thereby promot ing smoothly functioning markets. This legislation is not intended to i nterfere with these critical functions. H o usE CoMM. oN ENERGY AND C o MMERCE, I N siDER TRADING AND SECURITIES FRAUD ENFORCE '.IENT ACT OF 1 988, H . R . REP. No. 9 1 0 , 1 00th Cong. , 2d Sess. 19 ( 1988), ,- eprinted in 1 988 U . S . C . C .A.N. 6043, 6056. As Professor B rudney observes, the search for relevant corporate and economic i nformation improves the functioning o f the capital m a rkets. Such a search entails research costs that will not be allocated for that purpose unless the investor is able to receive the rewards of the informational benefits so obtained. Brudney, supra note 1 3 , at 34 1 . On the other hand, i t is possible that the selective favorable treatment o f the financial community leads to excessive research and competition for superior i n formation. m Modern portfolio theory suggests that i t is i mpossible to outperform the stock market systematically without the use of nonpublic information. See, e.g. , Macey, supra note 44, at 21 n.55. m Professor Coffee explains that the disclosure provisions of the Securities Exchange Act cf 1 934 actually subsidize the i nvestigatory activities of investment a nalysts by providing them with extensive detailed information at low cost-information that is more useful to the professional analyst than the individual trader. John C. Coffee, Jr., Market Failure and r h e Economic Case for a Manda tory Disclosure Sys t e m , 70 VA. L. REv. 7 1 7 , 7 2 8 - 29 ( 1 984 ) . """ See, e.g. , Stanford J . Grossman, On t h e Efficiency o f Cumpetitiue Stock Markets Where Trc.des Ha ve Diverse Inform a t io n , 31 J. FIN. 573, 574 ( 1976 ) ; Stanford J . G rossman & Joseph E. Stiglitz, Information and Competitive Price Sys tems, 66 AM. EcoN. REv. 246, 248 ( 1 9/6 ) . G rossman argues that i t would b e paradoxical to conclude that markets are per fectly efficient given the superior information and returns attributed to analysts. H e there fore concludes that analysts are able to d iscover information that is not fu l l y retlected in I j '·I .J 1 l i INSIDER TRADING 1 99 1 ] 231 ti ve, analysts may have access t o information that is not available to the general public.225 The policy of permitting corporations to ma k e disclosures by tipping analysts is one plausible explanation of how analysts gain such access.226 Der egulation of insider trading would have two effects on ana lysts , effects that this Article will describe as the "better source effec t " and the " embarrassment effect. " The better source effect reflects the fact that an analyst's information is seldom as good as a true insider tip. In a world in which insider trading and tipping are legal, investors would have access to a marketplace of better information than that provided by analysts, rendering the analyst's information second-rate. 227 The embarrassment effect results from the fact that a free flow of inside information would result in the entry into the marketplace of superior information to that pro vided by the analyst-information resulting from tipping and in formation generated by the occurrence of insider trades. This in formation would be likely to make the analyst's information appear dated and of poor quality. The derogation of the analyst's information would generate the implicit message that the analyst is not really a high-level specialist and does not provide a valuable service to investors.228 A second group threatened by insider trading is the professional stock p r i ces. 22 5 Indeed, through t h e i r practice o f selective d isclosure, analysts may further i n forma tional d isparities in t h e market. A s P rofessor Langevoort observes, the analyst may favor the high - paying i n st itutional investor over t h e retail c l i e n t . Langevoort, supra note 1 90, a t 1 04�3; see a lso F l e i schman, Presentation, s upra n o t e 220. 226 See supra notes 193, 2 1 5 - 2 1 8 . This p o l i cy does not, however, answer concerns raised by advocates of the l e ve l - p l aying-fi e l d approach to the securities markets that analysts' pos session of t h i s informational advantage is unfair. For exam p l e , the analysts i n S t euens did not d isclos e their superior i n formation to the world; they simply told a few o f their favored clients, who were a b l e to s e l l t h e i r hold i ngs in the computer and d efense equipment manu facturer a n d avoi d losses. See Ex - CE O , supra note 143, at 4:3 9. 22 7 In countries i n which insider trading prohibitions are absent or loosely e n forced, the value of inside information i s so s i g n i ficant as to cause investors to advertise for s u c h i n for mation openly. See How Asia Regards Insider Trading: A wareness Up But Some Countries Ca ll It Part of Business. LA TIMES, Mar. 28, 1 989, § 4 , at 9 ( describing p r actice i n New Zealand of traders running newspaper ads openly asking for inside information a t h e i g h t of pr e - O ctober 1 987 b u l l market). '"" The e m barrass ment effec t partially explains why ana lysts feel the need to tread c lose to the legal line by attempting to fe rret out informat i o n that i s not w i d e l y available public. See D i rks v. S E C , 4 6 3 U . S . 6 4 6 , 6 5 8 - 5 9 ( 1 9 8 : )) . to the 232 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 26: 1 7 9 investors.229 This diverse grou p m ight be viewed broadly as inclu d ing risk arbitrageurs,230 broker-dealers trading for their own ac counts,231 and institutional investors, such as mutual funds, pen sion funds, and insurance companies. Investment p rofessionals spend a great deal of money to acquire su p erior m arket and firm information. Although they do not have the access of an inside r, their resources enable them to be " next in line" in terms of quality of information.232 To the extent that insiders are able to trade, they preempt or reduce the p rofessional investors' informational advantage.233 Stockholders of publicly held companies are also direct benefi ciaries of the regulation of insider trading. The existing regulation allows stockholders to be p assive. Stockholders need not weigh the costs and benefits of allowing insiders to trade the cor p oration's stock or monitor the agency p roblems that may result from such trading.234 If insider trading p roblems were relegated to state - law derivative suits , based on allegations of breaches of the insider's fiduciary duty or duty of loyalty, the burden of enforcement would be on stockholders. Instead , the SEC has assumed the enforcement 229 As Professor Langevoort explains, professional investors benefit from insider trading regulation because they are " 'next i n line' [ after corporate insiders] w ith respect to the opportunity to trade immediately upon d i sclosure. " Langevoort, supra note 5 , at 400 n.6. 2 3 0 Arbitrageurs generate profits through i n- depth monitoring o f corporations coupled with large i nvestments when those corporations present "tradi ng opportunities." The arbi trageur is rewarded when this monitoring results i n timely i n formation o f which h e can take advantage by taking a large position before that i n formation is fully reflected i n the market place. In a sense, the arbitrageur profits from the fact that the securities markets are not perfectly efficient. The public announcement of material effects is not i m m e d i ately reflected i n stock prices; the market requires an adj ustment period. Arbitrage u rs are threatened by insider tradi ng because such trading is able to beat them at their own game. Not only can insiders profit from i n formation before it is available to arbitrageurs, but the leakage effect of their trading also may reduce the trading opportuni ty available to the arbitrageur. 23 1 To the extent that an analyst makes proprietary investment decisions as opposed to rendering investment advice to others, this category overlaps with the previous one. ' 3 2 Langevoort, supra note 5 , at 400 n.6. P rofessional investors also serve as major cus tomers of securities analysts. 2 3 3 This is not to say that the i n formational advantage of the professional i nvestor is a bad thing. To the extent that professionals expend resources to gathe r securities i n forma tion, they improve market efficiency. See Easterbrook, supra note 37, at 329-30 ( arguing that i n formation is quickly reflected by stock prices and that it "would be a colossal waste i f the information . . . had t o b e presented t o everyon e " ) . "'' See, e.g. , Roberta Romano, Metapo litics a n d Corpora te Law Reform , 36 STAN. L . REv. 923, 1 004-0.S ( 1 98 4 ) (explaining that governm ent intervention to regulate insider trading ad dresses stockholder free -rider problem and lowers agency costs) . 1 99 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 233 r ol e. Absent this enforcement, stockholders would have to exercise m ore vigilance in monitoring the extent and cost of insider trading in their corporations. Moreover, returning insider trading regula tion to the purview of such common-law doctrines would rekindle th e ongoing debate over the efficacy of using the stockholder deriv ative suit to enforce insiders' fiduciary duties to the corporation.235 Most importantly, the general public, unexposed to m any of the le gal analyses d iscussed above, appears to believe that insider trad ing is harmful to the markets . The concepts of insider trading as . unfair, as misappropriation of corporate property, and as destruc tive of investor confidence, while controversial and vigorously de bate d among scholars,236 reflect the perception of the average stockholder. Stockholders, rightly or wrongly, are likely to view in sider trading regulation as an effective way of disciplining their corporate managers with little cost or effort. This feeds into the p opular mentality23 7 that "greed is bad. "238 In the view of typical members of the public, someone who trades on inside information obtains a benefit from information for which he has not paid, information in which the trader has no ownership interest or other legitimate expectation of gain. The successful in side trader has won the lottery without buying a ticket. While they may be jealous of the trader's good fortune, typical members of the public see no reason to approve of activity in which they cannot also participate and which leads to what they perceive as unde served gains. 239 Thus, it is p ossible to identify at least three politically signifi cant groups that benefit from the current regulation of insider trading. Securities analysts and professional investors support in230 For a sampling of the l iterature addre5sing whether the derivative suit effectively de ters management misconduct, see Daniel R . Fischel & Michael Bradley, The R o le o f Liabil ity R ules and t h e Derivative Suit in Corporate Law: A Theore tica l and Empirical A n a ly sis, 71 CoRNELL L. REv. 26 1 , 262 n.2 ( 1 986) . 236 237 See supra note 1 8 1 . See Langevoort, supra note 5 , a t 400 - 0 1 ( describing restriction o f insider trading as "emotional in its genesis" and as political attempt to satisfy "those who feel u nfairly disad vantaged by the absence of power, size, or status"). 2 36 H ence the villain in the movie WALL STREET, Gordon Gekko, can b e i dentified by his philosophy: " Greed . . . is good." WALL STREET ( 20th Century Fox Film Corp. 1987 ) . 239 Judge Posner terms regulation fueled by a public feeling o r concern rather than an economic or utilitarian analysis "public sentiment statutes." Richard A . Posner, Economics, Politics and the Reading of S t a t u tes and the Cons t i t u t io n , 49 U. CHI. L REv. 263, 287 ( 19 8 2 ) . Insider trading legislation may be a prime example of a public sentiment statute. 234 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 26 : 1 7 9 sider trading regulation and strict enforcement efforts by the SEC240 because, after insiders, they are the next best able to obtain and use market-sensitive information .241 Stockholders support in sider trading regulation b ecause of their perception that insider trading is harmful and because it is easier to have that j udgment made by Congress than to analyze the question firsthand. In contrast, those who oppose such regulation are n ot in a posi tion to mount a public campaign for deregulation . C orporate insid ers would betray their beneficiaries by endorsing a regulatory sys tem that allows insiders t o exploit their positions for private gains. Individual tippees generally receive inside information on an un predictable and fortuitous basis. Absent systematic access to such information , they are not likely to agitate for change. Temporary insiders, such as lawyers and investment bankers, risk the same type of disapprobation as that faced by traditional insiders if they support deregulation . In addition, promoting the freedom of pro fessionals to trade on information provided by their clients would be l ikely to result in contractual modification that, at a minimum, would require the outsiders to disgorge such trading profits to their corporate clients . This combination of public disapproval and i ndustry support virtually guarantees the continued regulation of insider trading. In dustry professionals constitute active and knowledgeable partici pants in SEC and congressional decisionmaking on regulation and enforcement of the securities markets. They often serve as advisors to Congress and are, directly and indirectly, the source of congres si onal perceptions as to the effect of insider trading regulation on the securities markets and the economy.242 Congress is particularly " " Some scholars, such as Professor Macey, argue that market p r o fess i o n a l s try to p e r s u a d e the p ub l i c t h a t i n s i d e r t r a d i n g i s w r o n g because t h e successful i n fl u e n c e o f p u b l i c o p i n i o n w i l l result i n increased r e g u l a t i o n a n d e n forcement of the p r o h i bition a g a i n st i n s i d e r s , and t h o s e who are next b e s t able to u s e the i n formation will p rofit thereby. Jonath a n R . Macey, Ethics, Econom ics, and Insider Trading. Ayn R a n d Meets the Theory o f t h e Firm, 11 HARV. J.L & Pus. PoL'Y 785, 803 ( 1 988). " " See David D . Haddock & ,Jona than R. Macey, Regula tion on Dema nd: A P r i va t e In t erest Model, with an Application to Insi der Trading Regu lation, 30 J L . & EcoN. 3 1 1 , 3 2 9 :30 ( 1 987) (arguing t h a t i nsider trad i n g regulation results i n greater d istr i b u t i o n of t r a d i n g p rofi ts to i n d ustry professionals than to gene ral p u b l i c and t h a t this d is t r i bution r e s u l t s i n pol itical efforts b y such professionals i n s u p p ort of greater regulation a n d e n fo rce m e n t ) . "" See id. a t 3 1 9 - 2 4 (desc r i b i ng i n s i d e r trading regulation as resp o n s i v e t o the p o l i tical consti t u ency that bene fits from such regulation, p r i m a r i l y market profess ion a l s ) . 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 235 unlikely to disregard the recommendations of these professionals in l ight of the public aversion to insider trading. A member of Con gress would be loathe to risk disapprobation by taking on the de regulation of insider trading, a reform that enjoys no substantial public support. IV. THE RESULT OF THE ANALYSIS: A NEW PROPOSAL FOR REGULATION O F INSIDER TRADING The foregoing analysis demonstrates that continued regulation of insider trading is likely because of political realities, regardless of whether economists can demonstrate an empirical effect of in sider trading on the market or advocates of market fairness can tie insider trading to the availability of capital. This Article also has demonstrated that the existing system of regulation is unsound and that the best justification for prohibiting insider trading is that insiders owe a fiduciary duty to the market not to abuse their position by taking personal advantage of nonpublic corporate information. Today, it appears that resistance to a statutory definition of in sider trading may be weakening; C ongress, commentators, and even the SEC have been attempting to draft a definition . 243 These principles may serve to inform decisions about the appropriate statutory scheme. In developing a statutory scheme, we should be aware that calling it a statutory definition of insider trading prejudges the issue. In the absence of a strict parity-of-information standard , the statute will be deciding, in effect, who should be free to use material nonpublic information. 143 A number of legislative proposals defining insider trading have been d eveloped in the past several years. These include a proposal d rafted by a group of private securities lawyers (the "Ad H oc Committee") at the request of Senators R iegle and D'Amato, which was intro duced as S. 1 380, lOOth Cong., 1 st Sess. ( 1 987) , reprin ted in Symposium, supra note 1 27 , at 531 -34 app.; a proposal developed by the New York Stock Exchange Legal Advisory C o m mittee, Report of the New York Stock Exchange Legal Advisory Committee, Proposed Stat utory Definition of Insider Trad ing ( 1 987), reprin t e d in Symposium, supra note 1 27 , ot 54344 a p p . ; and a proposal prepared by the SEC, reprinted in Symposium, s u p ra note 127. at .) 35-42 app., which was subsequently modified to conform to the approach of the Ad Hoc Committee's proposal. See SEC Modified Proposal, supra note 1 27 . Congress req uested that members of the Ad Hoc Comm ittee meet with the SEC and prepare Reconcili ation Draft of S. 1 380, repri n t ed in Symposium, supra note 1 27 , at .5 52-58 app. The draft never game;-ed the full support of e ither the Committee or the SEC. For a detailed analysis of these propos als, see P h il l ips '� Lavoie, supra note 5 , at 457-62. GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W 236 [Vol. 2 6 : 1 7 9 The proposal suggested by this Article departs most radically from existing proposals and literature by rejecting the focus on the method by which a trader acquires nonpublic information. By pre mising liability on an insider's duty to the marketplace, this propo sal is able to avoid the quagmire of analyzing the method of acqui sition, as well as the private contractual and other relationships between the trader, the issuer, and the source of the information. The current proposals for a statutory definition of insider trading analyze whether the information has been acquired wrongfully.244 Through the requirement of wrongfulness, they attempt to incor porate current law on breach of duty, breach of relationship of trust and confidence, and so forth. 245 This approach is misguided. Additionally, regulation of insider trading would be improved by reclassifying such trading as a regulatory violation rather than a crime. A complete examination of the effect of decriminalizing in sider trading is beyond the scope of this Article, but it should be noted that Congress would be justified in prohibiting a broader range of trading, based on concerns about market fairness, if such trading were not penalized by criminal sanctions. Given the lack of consensus on whether insider trad ing should be regulated and, if so, the justification for such regulation, it is sur prising that insider trading has generated so much recent media and enforcement attention. Although public and j udicial opinion appear to condemn insider trading as the moral equivalent of theft,246 it is not clear that this perception is accurate. Treating "" See, e.g , S . 1 380, l OOth Cong. , 1 st Sess. § 2 ( b) ( l ) ( 1 98 7 ) (prohibiting use of nonpublic i n formation i f trader " kn ows or i s reckless i n not knowing that such i nfor mation h as been obtained wrongfully, or i f the p urchase or sale of such security would constit ute a wrongful use of such i n formation " ) , repri n t e d i n Symposium , s upra note 1 27 , at 532 a p p . ; SEC Mod i fied Proposal, s upra note 1 27 , § 2 ( b) ( l ) ( prohibiting use of nonpublic i n form 3.tion if trader " knows or recklessly d isregards that such i n formation has been obtain e d wrongfully, or that such purchase or sale would constitute a wrongful use of such information " ) . 140 See, e.g. , S. 1 380, lOOth Cong. , 1st Sess. § 2 (b ) ( l ) ( 1 987) ( reconci l i ation d r a ft ) , re- pri n t ed in Symposium, supra note 1 27 , at 554 app. For the purposes of this subsection, such trading while in possessi o n o f mate rial, nonpublic i n formation is wrongful only if such information has been ob tained by, or its use would constitute, d i rectly or indirectly, ( A ) theft , bri bery, m isrepresentat ion, espionage (through electroni c or other means) or ( B ) con \'ersion , m isappropriation , a breach of any t!duci ary duty, any p e rsonal or other relationship of trust and confidence, or any contractual or employ m e n t relationship. "" For examp l e , the Second Circuit described i nsider trading in Un i t e d S t G t e.' L'. Carp r> n - 1991] INSIDER TRADING 237 insider trading as stealing is consistent with a property-rights ap proach, but if the regulation is refocused on the harm to the mar ketplace and the insider's duty to disclose to that marketplace , the insider trading violation might more accurately be likened to lying. A moral evaluation of lying, however, is more difficult. Societal views of lying are equivocal: society treats some lies as worse than others.247 lVIoreover, in view of the fact that insider trading results only in omissions and not in affirmative misrepresentations, it is not necessarily the moral equivalent of lying. There is a distinction in moral terms between affirmative misrepresentations and omis sions. To a certain extent, it is anomalous that the jurisprudence of common -law fraud has accepted the concept that liability may be predicated upon material omissions,248 a concept that has worked its way into statutory theory as well. Traditional philosophical the ory supports the view that it is far worse , from a moral perspective, to mislead than simply to omit relevant facts of which no inquiry has been made.249 Indeed, this principle is reflected in current ju risprudence. 250 These philosophical roots support the argument that insider trading is not the moral equivalent of lying.2 5 1 If insider trading cannot readily be equated with either stealing or lying, it is difficult to condemn such trading as i mmoral or in herently wrong. Therefore, from a moral perspective, classifying such trading as criminaP52 and penalizing it with stiff prison ter as " conduct constituting secreting, stealing, [or] purloin i n g . " 7 9 1 F . 2d 1 02 4 , 10:3 1 (2d C i r. 1 986). 247 See, e.g. , SISSELA BoK. LYING: M o RAL C H OICE I N P UBLIC AND PRIVATE LIFE ( 1978) (ex amining reprehensi b i l i ty of lying i n variety of settings ) . " " ' Such liability requires, of course, t h e presence of a d uty. S e e supra P a r t LA ( d iscuss ing requirement of d uty to d isclose in classical theory of insider tra d i n g ) . "" See, e.g . , MARCUS CICERO. D E OFFICIIS B K . III 321 ( W . M i l l e r t r a n s . 1 968) ( " ' I t is o n e thing to conceal,' . . . , ' not to reveal i s q uite a d iffer e n t thing. ' " ) . F o r a d e t a i l e d analysis o f the relative ethical or m o ral culpabili ty of nondisclosure and m isrepresentation as viewed by a number of classic- philosophical scholars, see Lawso n , supra note 1 2 5 , at n 7 - 4:3. ""'' See supra note 189 ( discussing n o n disclosure in Texas G u lf Sulphur case). 2" I f i nsider trading constitu tes lying, decisions by insiders based o n n onpublic informa tion to refrain from trading should also be actionable as fraudulent omissions. Insider non trading, al though perhaps d i fficult to prosecute, presents the same moral issue as i nsider trad ing. See Easterbrook, supra note 37, at 336-37 ( arguing that i n s i d e r nontrad ing may atfect stock pri ces just as insider tradi n g does). Nonetheless, a decision by an insider or tippee to refrai n from selling stock, for example, based on superior i n formation about an upcoming corporate development, is apparently legal. 2 52 S e e , e.g. , WAYNE R. L A F A V E & AusTIN W . Sc oTT, JR. H A NDBOOK O N C R I M I N A L L..>.w § 1 . 2 , at 1 1 (2d ed. 1 986) (explaining that major purpose of criminal laws i s enforcement o f 238 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 2 6 : 1 79 sentences should be reconsidered. 253 THE FIRST REQUIREMENT: INSIDER STATUS A. Although the presence of a fiduciary duty may be a factor in determining insider status , it should not determine when informa tion can be used as a basis for trading.254 Rather, a legislative solu tion should focus on defining the insider class. 255 Once the class is defined, thereby identifying the c lass of persons for whom the per sonal use of nonpublic information breaches their duty to the mar ketplace, insider class status alone should be the basis of restrict ing trading.256 Status as an insider should be determined by society's idea of morality); cf. Ronald J . Rychlak, Society 's Mora l Right t o Punish: A Fur t h er Explora tion of the Denunciation Theory of Punishm e n t , 65 TuL. L. REv. 299, 329 ( 1 990) ( " [ N ] ot a l l crimes are i m moral, and not all immoral acts are cri m inal. " ) . 203 Although the EEC Insider Dealing D i r ective prohibits insider trading, it does not re quire member states to make such trading criminal. See genera lly Raffael l o Fornasier, The Direc tive on Insider Dea ling, 13 FoRDHAM lNT'L L.J 1 49 ( 1 990) (discussing legal basis and effects of EEC I nsider Dealing D i rective ) ; Hopt, s upra note 18, at 56-57 ( arguing that by leaving sanctions to member states, d irective i s a compromise) . n • The d i fficulty o f applying the duty approach i s aptly illustrated by both Reed and Chestman. I n Reed, the court searched through principles of trust law, fiduciary law, and even the law of restitution i n an attempt to locate some clear standard as to when an action able breach of duty results from betrayal of a fam ily confidence. See United States v. Reed, 6 0 1 F. Supp. 685, 703 - 1 8 ( S . D . N . Y . ) , rev 'd in part o n other grou nds, 7 7 3 F . 2d 477 ( 2 d Cir. 1985). Notably, although the court did not go so far, sources relied on by the court suggest that a close fam i ly relationship is, by itself, sufficient to confer a relationship of trust and confidence. See 4 GEORGE E. PALMER, THE LAw OF RESTITUTION § 1 9 . 3 , a t 1 1 3 ( 1978) (ex plaining that "there is a strong inclination to find a confidential relationship from the fact of a close family connection ") (quoted in Reed, 601 F. Supp. at 7 10 ) . Additionally, predicating insider trading liability on the breach of a fiduciary duty would, presumably, allow a corporation to authorize i nsiders to trade i n its securities by submitting the issue to the board or the shareholders for approval. Wolfson, supra note 197, at 1 1 3. 205 As the Supreme Court explained in Dirks, the point of insider trading regulation is " to focus on policing insiders and what they do . . . rather than on policing i n formation per se and its possession . " D irks v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 663 ( 1 983) ( quoting In re I nvestors Mgmt. Co., 44 S.E.C. 63:3, 648 ( 19 7 1 ) (Smith, C., concurring in result) ) . 206 The idea of a status-based restriction has its seeds i n the insider trading regulations of Great Britain, which, inter alia, restrict trading by persons " connected with" a company. " Connected with" means holdi ng a position such as d irector, officer , or e mp l oye e , or having a professional relationship, such as a lawyer-client relationship, that affords access to non public information. See Company Securities ( Insider Dealing) Act, 1 985, ch. 8 ( Eng. ) . The provisions of the B ri tish statute are described i n Mark A. S p i tz , Note, Recent Developments in Insider Trading Laws a n d Problems of Enforcement in Great Brita i n , 1 2 B . C . INT'L & Cmw L REv. 265, 2 7 5 - 8 3 ( 1 989 ) . The EEC I nsider Dealing Directive also focuses on status as a hasis for l iabil ity, although it defines " insider" broadly, including within that category v i rtually ail persons who have a relationsh i p with the 1ssuer and obtain i nformation by vir- .l 1 I l I I � .j l ; 1 1 99 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 239 considering the objectives of market regulation rather than princi ples of agency law. Viewing insider trading regulation in terms of market regulation does not place the emphasis on harm to the cor poration or its stockholders, issues more appropriately left to state fiduciary law.257 Moreover it makes no sense to focus on the wrong ful nature of acquisition; there is no tie between injury to the in formational source and the obj ectives ·of securities regulation . Rather, the definition should be designed to address the harm that insider trading causes to the marketplace.258 One important element of the regulation is its relationship to the statutory disclosure system. To the extent that an insider controls disclosure of corporate information, that insider has not only supe rior access to information but also the opportunity to manipulate the timing and quality of disclosure. Limiting the incentives for such manipulation serves the objectives of prompt and complete disclosure as well as the insider trading regulation objectives of market fairness. Accordingly, the class of insiders should include those who are in a position to control corporate disclosure. In addition , much of the perceived unfairness of insider trading is based on the idea that management is able to beat the market; even in circumstances in which information is disclosed promptly, management is able to trade immediately prior to or concurrently with the disclosure, ob taining as a windfall the value of the market reaction to that dis closure .259 Thus, corporate insiders have an unerodable advantage in terms of access. The quality of this advantage depends, in part, on the level of the employee. High-level employees have a system atic advantage in terms of access because they are in a position to tue o f that relationshi p , as well as tippees. See H op t, supra note 1 8, at 62 -65 (describing groups included by directive i n category o f insider ) ; see a lso Langevoort, supra note 5, at 4 1 1 (suggesting system o f insider trading regulation that focuses on whether trader has " po sition of access " ) . " " ' See Barbara A . A s h , State R eg u lation o f Insider Trading - A Tim e ly Resurgence?, 4 9 O H I O ST. L.J. 393, 398 ( 1 988). '"" See supra n ote 181 (discussing possible harms of i nsider trading to marketplace ) ; see a lso H .R REP. No. 1 383, 73d Cong., 2d Sess. 1 1 ( 1 934) ( discussing importance of disclosure in functioning of markets and correlating market price with value ) . " [T ] h e hiding and se creting o f i mportant i n formation obstructs the operation of the markets as i ndices of real value." !d. '"" See SEC v . Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 401 F.2d 833, 853-54 nn. l ? - 1 9 (2d Cir. 1 968) (en bane ) ( d iscussing timing of ord ers p laced by insiders ) , cert. den ied, 394 U . S . 976 ( 1 969 ) . .l 240 GEOR GIA LA W R E VIE W [Vol. 2 6 : 1 79 learn about all significant corporate events as well as plans for dis closure of those events. It is important not to draw the class of insiders too broadly. The superior access of corporate employees must be balanced against the difficulty an employee may have in determining, before the fact, whether he is in p ossession of ma t eria l nonpublic i nforma tion. Virtually any employee is likely to have an advantage over the general public in evaluating his own company, but this superi ority alone should not preclude the employee from trading. Assum ing employee stock owr.ership is desirable,260 deeming this advan tage unfair is overbroad. Moreover, for lower-level employees, unlike officers and directors, the trading opportunities created by exposure to significant corporate events are likely to be random and occasional i n nature and are less likely to interfere with corpo rate decisionmaking. Occasional access to nonpublic information can be addressed through the category of secondary insiders de scribed below. For purposes of section 1 6 of the Exchange Act, insiders are de fined as officers, directors, and ten percent stockholders. 261 This proposal takes that definition as the starting point for purposes of insider trading and includes those persons as "primary insiders"262 zao The practice of permitting corporate insiders to trade the stock of their company is generally defended on the grounds that this practice aligns management i nterests more closely with those of the stockholders and minimizes the agency costs associated w i th the separation of ownership from control in the large publicly held corporation. See generally Eugene F. Fama, Agency Problems a n d the Theory of the Firm, 88 J. PoL. EcoN. 288 ( 1980 ) ; Oliver Hart, A n Economis t 's Perspective on t h e Theory o f the Firm, 8 9 CoLUM. L . REv. 1 757 ( 1 989); M ichael C . Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Manageri a l Beh a v i o r , Agency Costs a n d Ownership Struct ure, 3 J. FIN. EcoN. 305 ( 1976 ) . A bsent such a view, corporate i nsiders could simply be precluded from trading i n their company's stock, a prac tice that would substantially reduce opportunities for insider trading. See Levmore, supra note 1 8 1 , at 1 29-32, 1 57-58 ( acknowledging systematic advantage that corporate insiders have when trading i n their company's stock and suggesting investment through blind trust as alternative remedy) . '"' See 1 5 U.S. C . § 78p ( 1 988) . 262 The terms "primary i nsiders" and "secondary insiders" were used by the European Economic Commission during its prep aration of the Insider Dealing Directive, although they do not appear in the d irective i tself. Hopt, supra note 1 8 , at 62. Usage of the terms herein dif!"ers in that the EEC used the term " primary i nsiders" to refer to all classes of persons who have a relationshi p with the issuer, including employees, lawyers, auditors, suppliers, etc . , and used the term " secondary insiders" to refer to tippees. !d. at 62-65. Because this proposal does not i mpose liability on the trading activities of tippees, it i s possible to be more precise i n the classification of insiders. 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 241 because they generally have (1) the ability to affect the content and timing of corporate disclosure; ( 2 ) regular access to informa tion on significant corporate events; and (3) the ability to affect the decisionmaking process about such events. This proposal then adds to the category of primary insiders other persons employed by the corporation who by virtue of their employment h ave regular acce ss to decisions on corporate p ol icy and disclosure. The purpose of this addition is to make the section 16 class of insiders more flexible by treating insider status as a function of responsibil ity and access as well as position.263 To this class of primary insiders, the proposal adds a second cat egory denominated " secondary insiders." Secondary insiders are those who by virtue of an employment or other contractual rela tionship receive nonpublic information relating to the issuer or its securities for the purpose of advising or rendering services to the corporation or its management.264 S econdary insiders include b oth outsiders, such as lawyers and investment bankers , who are hired to advise or represent the corporation,265 and employees who have 26 3 The modification is akin to that introduced by the SEC in its recent amendments to the regulations under section 1 6 , in which the SEC determined that the category of officer should be defined in terms of " policy-making function" rather than title. See 17 C . F . R . § 240. 1 6 a - 1 ( f) ( 1991 ) . 264 The receipt o f nonpublic information b y a secondary insider need not b e a regular occurrence; insider status under this provision may be based on an isolated exchange of information, such as that which occurs when a lawyer is hired to represent a corporation with respect to a single transaction. 26 0 The proposal would not classify as insiders those traders sometimes described as " market insiders" ( i. e . , those who by virtue of their position or the types of services they perform have regular industry access to nonpublic information ) . See Maria T. Galena, Note, Drawing the Line on Insiders and Outsiders for Rule l Ob-5: C hiarella v. U ni ted S tates, 4 HARV. J . L. & P u s. PoL'Y 203, 233-41 ( 1 981 ) (arguing that those with regular access to non public information should be treated as insiders based on claim that those traders breach their duty because they have obtained information " by virtue of a structura: position within the market"). The use by market insiders of nonpublic information can take two forms: insiders may trade on the information directly or allocate the information, effecting wealth d istribution through d isclosure to clients. The former problem can be addressed by prohibiting analysts or their firms from trading on nonpublic information. Such a prohibition would not affect the market d issemination function addressed by Congress and the Supreme Court. See supra notes 220-22 1 . The latter problem was the basis for the D istrict o f Columbia Ci rcuit's concern i n Dirks. See Dirks v. SEC, 681 F.2d 824, 840 - 4 1 (D.C. Cir. 1982 ) , rev 'd, 463 U.S. 646 ( 1 983); see a lso supra note 225 ( discussing analysts' selective disclosure as aggravating existing informa tional disparities ) . It is clearly possible to conclude, as the court did in Dirks, 681 F . 2d a t 840-42, that securities professionals, by virtue of their position, owe fiduciary duties to the 242 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 access t o nonpublic corporate information o n an irregular o r infre quent basis. 2 66 Trading by the above-described classes of insiders would be re stricted as follows: it would be a violation of federal law for pri mary insiders who possess material nonpublic information relative to any security,267 obtained by virtue of their status as an insider, to take advantage of that information by trading or tipping.268 It would be a violation of federal law for secondary insiders who pos sess material nonpublic information relative to any security, ob tained by virtue of their relationship with the corporation, to take advantage of that information by trading or tipping. Trading by either class of insiders would be defined to include effecting trades, for the insider's personal account or the account of others, on the basis of nonpublic information. The provision would contain a statutory presumption that an insider who possesses m aterial non public information has based his trading on that information; this p resumption could be rebutted through a showing, by the insider, of a distinct legitimate basis for the trading in question. B. THE MEANING OF INSIDE I NFORMATION Removing the emphasis on fiduciary duty demonstrates that a major issue in defining insider trading is the question of what con stitutes inside information. Although many issues are presented in constructing a statutory definition of inside information , including specifying when information is material and when it is n onpublic, market at large not to engage i n selective d isclosure of nonpublic i n formation. B ecause se curities professionals, i ncluding i n vestment advisors, and registered broker-dealers like D ir ks , are heavily regulated by the federal securities laws, such duti es also can be i m p osed directly by statute. As the court i n Dirks observed, however, the obligations o f securities professionals i n this regard are distinct from the generally applicable antifraud provis ions. I d. Accordingly, they should be addressed separately. 266 The European Insider Dealing Directive classifies certain government officials as insid ers based on their access to market-sensitive i n formation. See Hopt, supra note 18, a t 6 2-65. The British regulations also prohibit trading by public servants. Spitz, supra note 2 56 , at 278; see a lso G alena, supra note 265, at 204 n.5 ( d iscussing insider status of government employees ) . Consideration of the appropriate treatment of government officials i s beyond the scope of this Article. 267 Because the proposal does not premise liabi lity on the breach of a fi duciary duty, i n siders violate t h e provision b y trading i n a n y security o f t h e issuer, whether i t i s d e b t or equity. See supra note 5 2 (debating whether trad ing i n debt securities violates current i n sider trad ing law) . 268 For an explanation of what constitutes impermissible tippi ng, see infra Part I V . C . 1991] INSIDER TRADING 243 one that seems most difficult is deciding when information is "in side" with respect to a class of insiders. Is an insider barred from trading on the basis of n onpublic information that relates only to the corporation to with the insider is connected269 or from using any information he receives by virtue of insider status, even if that information relates to the stock of another issuer? Both the British statute and the EEC directive seek to prohibit the use of any information acquired by virtue of the insider's sta tus or position,270 but it is not clear that this broad scope is appro priate. Again , it is necessary to look at the rationale behind the prohibition and the availability of alternative methods of regulation. The economic rationales for prohibiting insider trading are weakest when the trader is an outsider with respect to the issuer of the securities traded. A corporate employee who learns, in the course of his employment, of information relevant to another is suer is not in a position to control disclosure of that information, to manipulate corporate events of the issuer, or to abuse a fiduci269 There are two separate issues in this analysis. F irst, does an outsider violate insider tradi ng rules by using information obtained by virtue of business relations with the source? And second , even if such trading would be permissible when effected by an outsider as prin cipal ( i.e., a corporation or an i nd ividual) , is it i l legal i f the outsider is an employee (or otherwise an agent) of a corporation and acquires the information by virtue of his employee status? 27 0 U nder the British statute, this issue was resolved by defining i nside i nformation, to i nclude i nformation relating to any actual or contemplated transaction between the insider's company and another company. Insiders are prohi b i te d from trading in the securities of the other company while i n possession of such i nformation. Thus, inside i n formation for pur poses of the B r itish law includes i nformation both about the issuer and about the issuer's transactions with other companies. Company Securities ( Insider Dealing) Act, 1 985, ch. 8 ( Eng. ) ; see S pitz, supra note 256, at 277. The coverage of the EEC I nsider Dealing Directive is s i mi lar. I t defines inside information as simp ly information which has not been made public of a precise nature relating to one or several issuers of transferabl e securities or to one or several transferable securities, which, i f i t were made public, would be likely to have a significant effect on the price of the transferable security or securities i n question. Council D irective 89/592 Coordinating Regulations on I nsider Deaiing, art. 1 , 1 989 O.J. (L 334) 30, 3 1 , quoted in Hopt, supra note 18, a t 57. Thus, i nside i nformation can relate to the securities or the issuer. U nder the directive's provisions, inside information cannot be uti l ized by insiders, who, for the p urposes of the D irective, i nclude, inter alia, anyone who obtains inside information by virtue of his profession, duties, or business relationship with the issuer. Thus, insiders m ight include suppliers, clients, or participants in a planned merger. Council Directive 89/592 Coordinating Regulations on I nsider Dealing, art. 2 , 1 989 O J. ( L 334) 30, :3 1 ; Hopt, supra note 1 8 , at 64. .• 244 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 ary pos1t10n with respect to the issuer's stockholders. Nor is the employee appropriating property that belongs to the issuer as long as the information was legally obtained by the employee or the corporate employer. Moreover, information relating to third par ties often falls within a grey area with respect to confidentiality. Although both the bidder and the target would hope to maintain confidentiality of information relative to a prospective tender offer, information relating to the business plans, orders for supplies, etc., may not be explicitly proprietary or secret.271 The British and EEC positions272 take the broadest approach, defining as inside information all material nonpublic information with respect to either the employer or the second corporation.273 The fact that information is nonpublic, however, does not make it either confidential or proprietary. As a practical matter, some in vestor is always going to be the first to discover new information about a company, and it seems unreasonable to disqualify the in vestor from using the information simply because he acquired it by virtue of employment. An alternative approach would include as inside information all material nonpublic information that either the target or the em ployer wants to keep confidentiaU74 The difficulty with this ap proach is that the ability of the investor to use the inform ation may depend on decisions of a corporation that does n ot employ him , to which he may owe no duties, and that, arguably, s hould not b e able to bind him. Moreover , the target clearly could not restrain third-party individuals or entities directly, absent a contractual agreement; it should not be able to restrain traders simply by vir tue of their status as corporate employees. "11 Both Rothberg v. Rosenbloom, 7 7 1 F . 2 d 8 1 8 , 820 ( 3d Cir. 1985 ) , see supra note 1 75 , and SEC v. L u n d , 570 F . S u p p . 1 3 9 7 , 1 4 0 1 ( C . D . C a l . 1983 ) , see supra n o t e 1 68, i n volved such nonproprietary i n formation. The ambiguity in both cases is i llustrated by the courts' assumptions that, although the i n d i vidual defendants ' trading was illegal, tradi n g by the defe n d ants' business employer would have been lega l . " ' " S e e supra n o t e 2 7 0 ( discussing B r i t i s h a n d EEC provisions). m Thus, under these definitions, both the tender offeror and the supplier i n the examples in Pare II.C. of this Article would be precluded from trading. The B ritish statute p rovides that a p rospective bidder may buy the stock of the target company in order to effect the takeover, but not otherwise. Company Securities (Insider Dealing) Act, 1 985, ch. 8, § 1 (5 ) ( Eng. ) . The provision is ambiguous as t o whether preannouncement trading b y t h e bidder is legal. " � ·• This p rovision could be strengthened by requiring that the corporation take affirma t i v e s t e p s to m a i n tain the confidential ity of the i n formation. "i I1 ll 1 i � � l 1 99 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 245 The third option is to preclude the employee from trading on i nformation that is confidential and proprietary in the hands of his e mployer. Thus , the test of whether information is " inside " under th is approach is not whether it relates to the securities of the com p any with which the insider is connected, but rather whether the corporation has some sort of interest, proprietary or property, in th e information. This test may be analogized to the corporate op portunity doctrine, in which a corporate employee may not appro priate a business opportunity that is of value to the corporation for his personal benefit.275 Whenever a corporate employee uses infor mation that has a value to his employer for personal use, there is a dive rsion of value from the corporation to the employee.276 This approach to inside information views a corporation's infor mation as a form of intangible property. The corporation may, through confidentiality regulations, employment contracts, or oth erwise,277 restrict its employees' abilities to use that information.278 m See, e.g. , Guth v. Loft, Inc. , 5 A.2d 503, 5 1 1 (Del. 1939) (discussing corporate opportu nity doctri n e ) . , 7 6 One m i g h t observe t h a t firms a r e taking a broader v i e w o f p roprietary i nformation in areas other than securities trading. For example, contractual arrangements that restrict an emp loyee's ability to compete with the firm after termina tion of employment are prem ised on the notion t h a t the firm has a proprietary interest i n the employee's human capital, the knowledge and skill acquired by the employee during his tenure at the firm. See K itch, supra note 198, a t 684-86 (describing fi r m 's interest i n "human capital " ) . 27 7 M any employer-employee cases present difficult problems o f proof under this ap proach because of the absence of any explicit effort by the employer to m a intain the infor mation as confidential. I t has been suggested that, even i n the absence of a written agree ment, there may be an implicit contractual agreement by the employee to maintain corporate i n formation as confidential. See Wolfson, supra note 197, at 1 07 -08. This is par ticularly true with respect to certain m arket-sensitive information such as the existence of merger negoti ations or a pending change in dividend policy, which is l ikely to be viewed by the corporation as confidential and treated as such even in the absence of contractual restrictions. 278 This a pproach conversely would permit corporations to opt out of insider trading regu lation, at least i n part, by refusing to treat corporate i n formation as proprietary or confiden tial. The treatment of information as intangible property would make the employee's use of the information a breach of his duty to the corporation based on the combination of the contractual provisions and the obligations of confidentiality thereunder. This definition is a way of clarifying the breach of duty articulated by the court in R o t h berg u. Rosenbloom. As the court stated, " [a ] n insider on either side of a proposed transaction violates the insider trading rule when he uses insider i n formation in violation of the fiduciary duty owed to the corporation to which h e owes a d uty of confidentiality." Rothberg v. Rosenbloom, 7 7 1 F.2d 8 1 8, 822 ( 3d Cir. 1985). The shortcoming i n the Rothberg court's analysis is i ts fai l u re to analyze the source of the defendant's d uty of confidentiality. Instead, the court seems to premise a general d u ty of con fidentiality on the general duties i n h e r e n t i n the e m p l oyment 246 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [ Vol. 26: 1 7 9 As a property rights theory, this approach i s logical. Moreover, this notion of insider trading bears the greatest relation to the agency principles from which insider trading liability has evolved. Finally, the least restrictive view of inside information is to cate gorize information as " inside" only if it relates to the issuer or the securities of the issuer to which the insider is connected.27 9 The justifications for this approach include the fact that only in this situation are concerns about manipulation, moral hazard, and de lay of disclosure j ustified. Moreover, this view of inside informa tion speaks to the rationale behind the level-playing-field theory of r egulation. Arguably, the situation in which insider trading is most unfair to the marketplace is the case in which a corporate insider, by virtue of his position, obtains material information that enables the insider to value the corporation's stock more accurately than outside investors. 2 80 C. REGULATION OF TIPPING The proposed provision would deal more harshly than current law with insiders who tip confidential information to others. Tip ping by insiders would be defined as selective disclosure of infor mation by an insider under circumstances in which trading by the insider would be illegal. The proposal presumes that such tipping benefits the insider, directly or indirectly.281 Accordingly, the pro vision would impose liability on tippers regardless of whether a pe- relationship. One difficulty with this approa;:;h is that i t does not limit the corporation's ability to re strict the use of corporate information. While certai n corporate i n formation, such as trade secrets or developments created by corporate action, may well b e p roprietary i n n a tu re , i t is not obvious that all corporate information is proprietary simply because i t comes i n to the possession of the corporation or because a corporation has property rights in all the i n for mation it possesses. For a detailed d iscussion of the Lockean theory of i n formation as prop erty and the corporation's rights to such property, see Lawson, supra note 1 25, a t 763-69. 2 ' " This definition of inside i n formation would make cross -trading legal. See supra note 1 7 1 ( discussing cross- tra d ing) . The same approach is taken by the 1988 J apanese statute. S h oken torikikihb ( S E L ) , Law No. 25 of 1 948, a m e n ded by Law to Amend a Part of the SEL, Law No. 7 5 of 1 988; see A kashi, Note, supra note 17, at 1 :306 - 1 0 . "' "0 See Akaski, Note, supra note 17, a t 1 3 1 2 (describing unfairness of allowing persons who have special relationship with issuer whereby they are able to generate, or at. least o b tai n , ready access to i n formation about issuer to use i n formation in trad ing w it h p u blic investors ) . "81 The case of an insider who tips by m istake could l:Je addressed by applying Rule l 0 b 5's requirement of scienter to i n s i d e r trading. See Ernst & Ernst v . Hochfelder, 4 2 .5 U . S . 1 8.5 , 1 99 ( 1 976 ) . Thus, t o be liable, t h e tipp ei must have acted with at least recklessness. 1991] INSIDER TRADING 247 c uniary motive could be established for tipping.2 82 Insiders would be liable for profits earned by tippee trading based on a two-part test. Insiders who disclose confidential corporate information to third parties who subsequently trade on that information would be liable for the profits earned through such trading, if the insiders acted negligently or wrongfully in disclosing the information283 and if the tippee's trading was reasonably foreseeable. The purpose of broadening liability for tippers is to deter the creation by corporate insiders of informational inequalities through selective disclosure. If insider trading is harmful to the markets because those on the inside enjoy unfairly superior access to infor mation compared to average investors , the types of insider-analyst relationships that create superior access should also be minimized. This formulation responds to two concerns: the SEC's concern that corporations improperly use investment analysts to make selective disclosure,284 and commentators' concern that investment analysts contribute to a market in which insiders in a broad sense, such as professional investors , have an unerodable and unfair informa tional advantage.285 While dealing more harshly with tippers , the proposed regula tion would abolish the regulation of insider trading by tippees. The only trading on the basis of nonpublic information that would be restricted is that engaged in by statutory insiders. 286 Rather, tippee 2 82 Thus, the provision would abolish the standard set by Dirks that an insider breaches his fiduciary duty by tipping only if he receives a pecuniary benefit thereby. D i rks v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 662-63 ( 1 98 3 ) . L iability would not require proof of financial gain or proof that the tipper intended to make a gift to the tippee. 283 In other words, an i nsider who d iscloses to a third party for transactional reasons (i.e., for a valid, non-disclosure-related corporate purpose) will not be liable i f the recipient of the i n formation uses the information to trade. The tippee may, however, incur liability as a secondary insider. For example, a corporate officer, who discloses a prospective tender offer to the fi rm's attorneys so they can assist with preparation of the tender offer documents, will not be l iable i f the attorneys trade on the i n form ation. The attorneys i n this case would be treated as secondary insiders u nd e r the statute. 28' Fleischman, P resentation, supra note 220. 28 " See supra notes 220-22 1 , 226 ( highlighting debate over whether analysts' informa tional advantage i s unfa ir ) . 28 " Thus, this proposal takes the opposite position from that o f the EEC d irective, which im poses liability on tippees "who with full k nowledge of the facts possess [ ] i nside informa tion, the direct or indirect source o f which could not be other than a [ pr i m a ry inside r ] . " H opt, supra note 1 8 , at 7 1 ( quoti n g I nsider Dealing D irective, a r t . 4 ( E EC ) ) . U n der the directive, t i p pees are prohibited from trading regardless of whether the primary insider has disclosed the information lawfully. ld . Thus, the directive also rejects the "wrongfulness" 248 GEOR GIA LA W RE VIE W [Vol. 2 6 : 1 7 9 trading would be regulated indirectly by requiring tippers to be responsible for the economic consequences of tippee trading.28 7 The rationale behind this provision is that the concept of deriva tive liability, or derivative duty, is too difficult to apply, both for the courts and for traders. It is impractical,288 and perhaps ineffi cient,289 to require a tippee to analyze the source of his i nformation to determine if, somewhere up the chain of information , there h as been a misappropriation or a breach of fiduciary duty. Indeed, the SEC appears to be making a practice of investigating and prose cuting tippees on circumstantial evidence that trading was based on inside information. 29 0 Some in the industry have described the focus of the draft congressional definitions. S e e supra notes 243-245 and accompanying text. 2 8 7 A l though circumstances i n which the tipper i s judgment-proof and the tippee has gar nered large trading profits appear to present an e n forcement problem, m ost such cases would never arise under this proposal. The common ( an d most troubling) obj ective for the tipper is pecuniary gain, and the disgorgement remedy addresses that gain. A dditionally, as a p ractical matter, most of those within the class of statutory insiders, by virtue of their position, will have attained substantial personal wealth such that, even if their motive for tipping in a particular case is not pecuniary, the risk of a severe monetary p e n a lty w i l l deter tipping. 28 8 Much of the information analyzed by traders and arbitrageurs consists o f market ru mors and " soft" information. Moreover, empirical evidence suggests that m a n y significant corporate disclosures are l eaked to the extent that the price of the stock has already begun to reflect the information prior to any public disclosure of the information. See, e.g. , Gregg A . Jarrell, Stock Trading Before the A nnouncement of Tender Offers: Insider Trading or Market A nticipation, 5 J.L. EcoN. & 0RG. 225, 226-27 ( 1 989) ( finding price of target compa nies i ncreased prior to first public announcement of a tender offer or merge r ) ; Paul H . Ma latesta & Rex Thompson, Partially A n t icipated Events: A Model of Stock Price R e a c t ions with a n Application t o Corporate A cquis i t ions, 14 J. FIN. EcoN. 237, 240 ( 1 985) (same ) ; see a lso Levinson v. B asic, Inc., 786 F.2d 7 4 1 , 744-45 ( 6th Cir. 1 986) (describing how stock price rose during merger negotiations despite public denials of corporate developments), vacated, 485 U.S. 224 ( 1 988). It may be virtually impossible for a market participant to engage i n the necessary line-drawing i n such cases. 289 See supra note 15 ( d iscussing Court's concern in Dirks that such a requirement would interfere with valuable function of market analysts) . 290 In a recent prosecution i n the Southern District of New York, for example, the SEC sought preliminary i nj unctive relief as well as an order freezing the defendants' assets, based solely on circumstantial evidence of insider trad i ng combined '>vith curiously timed trades. SEC v. Foundation Hai, 736 F . Supp. 465, 4 7 1 -73 ( S.D.N.Y. 1990 ) . The d istrict court granted the requested relief but was reversed in part by the Second C ircuit, which, a lthough not condemning the SEC's fai lure even to identify the alleged tipper, found that the SEC had not established a prima facie case entitling it to injunctive relief. SEC v. U ni fu n d SAL, 910 F.2d 1 028, 1037 (2d Cir. 1990 ) ; see a lso SEC v. H e ider, No. 90 Civ. 4636, 1 990 U.S. D ist. LEXIS 1 6246, at * 1 1 - 1 2 (S.D.N.Y. Dec. 3, 1 990) ( d enying motion to dismiss complaint that fai l ed to identify tipper). Defendant Heider explained his curiously timed trading to the SEC by stating that he " ' overheard discussion in a restaurant to the effect that the price of Conte! s tock would i ncrease because somethi ng was going to happen with the company. ' " 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 249 SEC's stance as prosecuting on the basis of " curiously timed trades. " Given the enforcement tools available to the SEC, it is difficult for traders to defend themselves against such prosecu tions , in which the SEC may require the trader to come up with ind ependent justification291 for his curiously timed trades. 292 In ad dition , the proposed judicial and statutory tests that require the tippee to have actual or constructive knowledge that he has re ceived inside information are difficult to apply to the realities of tipping situations.293 Nor does tippee trading implicate the economic obj ectives of early and complete disclosure that underlie regulation of insider trading. A tippee is not in a p osition to control disclosure or to manipulate corporate affairs to create trading opportunities. More over, to the extent that tipping is harmful to the firm's interests, the penalty for tipping should be borne by the tipper, who is re sponsible ;or protecting those interests.294 Finally, by imposing substantial civil liability on tippers, it is likely that the practice of tipping, whether for profit or otherwise, will be adequately Isabelle C lary, Court Freezes Assets in Suspected Cont e l Insider Trading Case , UPI, July 23, 1 990, availa b le in LEXIS, Nexis Library, UPI file. ""' For example, the d e fendant in United States v. Chestman, 947 F.2d 55 1 (2d Cir. 1 99 1 ) ( e n bane ) , explained h i s trades i n Waldbaum stock t o the SEC b y stating that the trades were the product of research " consistent with previous purchases of Waldbaum stock and other retail food stocks and were supported by reports i n trade publications as well as the unusually high trading volume of the stock on Nov. 25." Id. at 555. 29 2 The implication is that a trader has not simply done a good job of analysis. The SEC has taken the position that, i f the trader demonstrates a pattern of anticipating market i n formation, such prescience i n dicates the use of inside i n formation rather than effective research techniques. '"' In Ches t m a n , for example, K e ith Loeb testified on behalf of the government that he told C hestman he had "some definite, some accurate i n formation" that would favorably af fect the price of Waldbaum stock . 947 F.2d at 555. Loeb did not explain the source of his i n formation or the basis for his belief that it was favorable. Id. A similar example is pro vided by Dennis Levine's description of the information h e gave to Ivan Boesky in his tips: I wasn't telling Ivan anything very specific-it was more a matter of suggesting that, say, his investment i n XYZ Corp. seemed worth holding on to. I never told him my oblique suggestions were based on nonpublic i nformation, but over time he evidently learned their value. Dennis B . Levine, The Inside S tory of A n Inside Trader, FoRTUNE, May 2 1 , 1 990, at 80. Levine did not disclose to Boesky his sources of information, which included both his em ployer, Drexel Burnham Lambert, Inc. , and investment bankers at other brokerage firms. I d. 29' O f course, these values are not served to the extent that tipping may further the inter ests o f the fi r m . See G arten, supra note 220, at 626-32. GEOR GIA LA W R E VIE W 250 [ Vol. 2 6 : 1 7 9 " nip [ped ] i n the bud."295 Although eliminating tippee liability would prevent prosecution of many outsiders for insider trading, the provision does not abol ish all remedies against those who acquire inside information through improper or illegal means. Outsiders who acquire informa tion through theft or the equivalent can be prosecuted under the existing criminal laws. A source of information that is otherwise injured or defrauded by an outsider trade also will be able to bring a civil claim under traditional common-law and contractual reme dies, such as a civil suit for theft of trade secrets or breach of a confidentiality agreement. Addition ally, in the case of a lawyer , ac countant, psychiatrist, or other professional who misappropriates confidential client information, the breach of a professional rela tionship of trust may be remedied through disciplinary proceed ings, which might result in disbarment, license revocation, or pub lic censure. PENALTIE S D. The penalties authorized under this proposal would be commen surate with those applicable to other violations of the securities laws. In particular, courts could order disgorgement fro m the tip per of up to three times any profit earned by insider trading.296 In addition, tippers, under this proposal, would be liable for up to three times the trading profits earned by their personal trading as well as the trading of their tippees. 20' As the Supreme Court explained: The true insider or the broker-dealer is a t the fountai nhead of the con fidential information . . . . I f the prophylactic purpose of the law is to restrict the use o f all material i n s i d e information until it i s m a d e available to t h e investing p u b l i c , then t h e most effective means of carrying o u t t h i s policy i s t o n i p i n the bud the source of the information, the tipper, by discouraging him from " mak ing the i nitial d isclosure which is the first step i n the chain o f dissem i n ation. " B ateman Eichler, H i ll Richards, Inc. v. Berner, 4 7 2 U.S. 299, 3 1 6 ( 1985) ( quoting Nathanson v. Weis, Voisin, Cannon, Inc., 325 F . Supp. 50, 5 7 - 58 ( S . D . N . Y . 1 97 1 ) ) . 206 The SEC m ight also be authorized to seek civil fines to enhance the fi nancial penalty for insider trading consistent with i ts recently provided power under Section 2 1 . See 7 8 U.S.C.A. § 78u(d ) ( 3 ) ( West Supp. 1 99 1 ) (authorizing im position of civil penalties for viola tions of securities laws ) . ., � 1 i ' 199 1 ] INSIDER TRADING 251 CONCLUSION Congress and the courts have spent the last forty years attempt ing to articulate a rationale for regulating insider trading. Most of the justifications for the current system of p rohibiting insider trad ing as securities fraud under SEC Rule lOb-5 are seriously flawed. Public perception of insider trading as a problem coupled with a securities industry that would be seriously inj ured by deregulation suggests that deregulation is unlikely. If regulation is to continue, Congress should replace the current regime with a statute that is clear and predictable. A statutory definition of insider trading would provide the requisite notice to traders of the p otential ille gality of their conduct and would not chill legitimate trading, thereby promoting market efficiency. This Article 's proposal attempts to replace the current system of regulation with more of a bright-line test. In so doing, it proposes three substantial changes: ( 1 ) moving the emphasis in insider trad ing enforcement from criminal prosecution to civil disgorgement; (2) changing the system to place the full burden of tippee trading on the insiders who act as sources of the tips; and ( 3 ) replacing the concept of regulation based on the trader's fiduciary and other du ties with a system of regulation based on insider status. These changes would produce a logical, coherent approach to insider trading regulation.