Malapportionment and ideological bias in Chilean electoral districts

Transcription

Malapportionment and ideological bias in Chilean electoral districts
MalapportionmentandideologicalbiasinChileanelectoraldistricts
JohnM.Carey
DartmouthCollege
http://sites.dartmouth.edu/jcarey/
November8,2015
Abstract
Chile'suniquetwo-memberdistrictlegislativeelectionswerelongcriticizedforthesharpseat
thresholdsthesystemimposedandformalapportionment.Bothcharacteristicsarewidely
regardedashavingbeenadoptedtofavortheideologicalrightovertheleft.Theelectoral
reformof2015replacedalmostallthetwo-memberdistrictswithhighermagnitudes,butit
reducedmalapportionmentmuchless,andtheChamberofDeputiesandSenateremainamong
themostmalapportionedlegislativechambersintheworld.Usinganewmeasureofdistrictlevelideologicalpreferencesbasedonpresidentialandmunicipalelections,however,this
analysisfindsnoevidencethatmalapportionmentproducedideologicalbiasinelectionssince
2000underthepre-reformsystem,northatitwillproduceanybiasinthenew,post-reform
districts.
Introduction
ChilecompletedalandmarkelectoralreforminMay2015,abandoningitsuniquesystemby
whichalllegislators,deputiesandsenatorsalike,wereelectedintwo-member(a.k.a.binominal)
districts.Inthenewsystem,districtmagnitudesrangefromthreetoeightintheChamberof
DeputiesandfromtwotofiveintheSenate.Criticsofthepre-reform,binominalsystemlong
heldthatitwasbiasedinfavorofChile'sideologicalright,bothbecauseofthelimitednumber
ofseatsineachdistrict,andbecauseofmalapportionment,whichisdiscrepancybetweenthe
shareofpopulationinadistrictandtheshareoflegislativeseatsitelects.
Inthispaper,IexaminemalapportionmentasapotentialsourceofbiasinChileanelections.
Specifically,IdocumentthelevelsofmalapportionmentinbothchambersoftheChilean
Congress,theChamberofDeputiesandtheSenate,undertheoldbinominalsystemandinthe
new,post-reformdistricts.Iexaminewhetherwhethermalapportionmentproducedideological
biasinrecentelectionsandwhetheritshouldbeexpectedtodosointhepost-reformsystem.
Usinganewmeasureofdistrict-levelideologicalpreferencesbasedonChileanpresidentialand
municipalelections,Ifindnoevidencethatmalapportionmentproducedideologicalbiasin
electionssince2000underthepre-reformsystem,northatitwillproduceanybiasinthenew
districts.
Ideologicalbiasunderthebinominalsystem
Thebinominalsystem'soriginsinthemilitarydictatorshipofGeneralAugustoPinochet
engenderedskepticismaboutitsfairness,andcriticsofthesystemhavelongarguedthatit
generatedbiasinfavoroftheideologicalright(Scully1997,Fuentes1999,Navia2005),themain
sourcesofwhichwereregardedtobe:
• SeatThresholds:Withtwo-memberdistrictsandthed'Hondtformula,thefirstseatis
awardedtothelargestlist,andthesecondtothesecond-largestlist,unlessthelargest
listmorethandoublesthevotetotalofthesecondlist.Ifthedistributionofvotes
acrosslistsissuchthatonecoalitionconsistentlyplacesfirst,butrarelydoublesthe
second-placecoalition,thesecond-placecoalitioncanconvertitsvotesupportinto
representationmoreefficientlythanthefirst-placecoalition–ararityintheworldof
electoralsystems(Rae1967).
• Malapportionment:Therewasinequalityofpopulationacrossdistricts,withdistricts
thatleanedtowardtheideologicalrightinitiallyfavoredwithmorelegislatorsper
populationthandistrictsthatleanedleft(RojasandNavia2005).
MostofthedebateoverbiasintheChileansystemfocusedonwhetherandhowseatthresholds
affecttheconversionofvotestoseatsbythemaincoalitionsthatdominatedChileanelections
fromre-democratizationin1989throughthelastelectionsheldunderthebinominalsystemin
2013.Notwithstandingsomecontributionsthatexpressskepticismabouttheextenttowhich
thebinominalsystemfavoredtheChileanrightovertheleft(Carey2003,Zucco2007),most
analysesconcludedthatthebinominalsystemwasadoptedtogenerateexactlysuchabiasand
waseffectiveindoingso(ScullyandValenzuela1997,Siavelis1997,Polga-Hecimovichand
Siavelisforthcoming).
Analysesofmalapportionmentweresomewhatlesscontentious.Siavelis(1997and200),Rojas
andNavia(2005),Auth(2014),ZapataLarrain(2014),andPolga-HecimovichandSiavelis(2015)
allconnectmalapportionmenttothemotivationsoftheelectoralsystemdesignersfromthe
1
outgoingmilitarygovernment.AlthoughthePinochetgovernmenthadalreadysettledonthe
binominalsystem,itundertooktore-drawthetwo-memberdistrictsafterthe1988plebiscite
thatrejectedanextensionofPinochet'spresidency.Undertherevisedmap,districtsthat
supportedPinochetintheplebiscitewereallocatedmoreChamberdeputiespercapitathan
weredistrictsthatsupportedthe"No"vote(ZapataLarrain2014).
Althoughmalapportionmentmayhavefavoredtherightintheearlypost-transitionelections,
however,anddespitethefactthatmalapportionmentitselfgrewmorepronouncedovertime,
bothRojasandNavia(2005)andZucco(2007)foundthatbytheearly2000s,changesinvoting
behaviorhadeliminatedthecorrelationbetweenthepopulationofagivenChamberdistrictand
thevotesharesofthetwomajorcoalitions.Theseanalyses,however,didnotestimatethelevel
ofbiasinSenateelections,wheremalapportionmentwasevenmorepronouncedandwhere
biasfromthe"originalsin"ofthesystem'sdesignmightthereforebeexpectedtobemore
enduring.
The2015reform
SomekeyelementsofChileanlegislativeelectionsremainintactfromthebinominaltothepostreformsystem.Legislatorsareelectedfromlistsnominatedbypoliticalparties,orbyalliances
thatcanincludecandidatesfrommorethanoneparty,andindependents.Thelistsareopen,
meaningthatvotersindicateapreferenceforanindividualcandidate.Votesforallcandidates
withinalistaretallied,andseatsareawardedfirsttothelistsusingthed'Hondtdivisors
formula,thencandidateswithinliststhatcapturedseatsareelectedinorderoftheirindividual
preferencevotes.Themainchangein2015isinthestructureofelectoraldistricts.Table1
illustratesthedistrictstructureofChileanChamberandSenateelectionsunderthebinominal
andthepost-reformsystems.
Table1.ChileanCongress–Districtstructurepre-andpost-reform
Chamber
Senate
Pre-Reform
Post-Reform
Pre-Reform
Post-Reform
NumberofDistricts
60
28
19
15
DistrictMagnitude
2
3–8
2
2–5
TotalSeats
120
155
38
50
Byincreasingdistrictmagnitudes,thereformraisedthenumberofdistinctseatthresholdsin
mostdistricts,dramaticallyreducingtheprospectthatthenationwidedistributionofloyalties
couldtranslateconsistentlyintobiasinseatdistributions.Thepost-reformsystemremains
substantiallymalapportioned,however,sothematterofbiasthroughmalapportionmentunder
thenewruleswarrantsrenewedattention.
Themalapportionmentremaininginthenewsystemreflectsthepoliticalbargainsnecessaryto
passanyelectoralreform.Between1990and2014,would-bereformersoffered26electoral
reformproposalsinChilebutneverassembledthesuper-majoritysupportrequiredtodispense
withthebinominalsystem(Anonymous2015,p.1).In2015,witheverypotentialvotein
supportcriticaltopassage,individuallegislatorswhoseelectoralprospectscouldbejeopardized
heldleveragetosettheallowableparametersforreform.Oneofthesewasthattheexisting
districtsmustbethebuildingblocksfornewdistricts,soasnotto"orphan"incumbent
legislators.Anotherwasthat,eventheleast-populateddistricts,magnitudewouldnotdecline
inSenatedistricts,andwouldincreasebyatleastoneseatfortheChamber.Thecartographers
2
alsosoughttoavoiddrawingnewdistrictsthatwouldpitincumbentsfromthesameparty
againstoneanother(Anonymous2015,pp.17-21).TheBacheletadministrationwenttogreat
lengthstoassurelegislatorsthattheirreelectionprospectswouldnotbedamaged,producing
simulatedoutcomesbasedonrecentelectionstoshowthat90%ofincumbentswouldbe
reelectedundertheproposedrules(Anonymous2015,p.18).Theconstraintsonbreakingapart
preexistingdistrictsandtheneedtoprotectincumbentlegislators'reelectionprospectslimited
thedegreetowhichthereformcouldreducemalapportionmentinChile.
MeasuringMalapportionment
Thestandardmeasureofmalapportionment,fromSamuelsandSnyder(2001)is:
MAL–(1/2)Σ|si–pi|
wheresigmastandsforthesummationoveralldistricts,siistheshareofseatsallocatedto
districti,andpiistheshareofthepopulationresidingindistricti.SamuelsandSnyder(2001)
measuredMALforelectednationallegislativechambersaroundtheworldasofthelate1990s.
Chilerankedasseverelymalapportioned,withitsSenateninthmostmalapportionedamong
upperchambers,anditsChamberofDeputiestheeleventhmostmalapportioned,amongthe78
countriesSamuelsandSnyderexamined.
AsRojasandNavia(2005)previouslydocumented,malapportionmentincreasedthroughthe
1990s,aspopulationsinmoredenselypopulated,urbandistrictsgrewmorerapidlythaninless
populatedones.Continuingthistrend,malapportionmentintheChamberofDeputiesrose
furtherinthefirstdecadeofthe2000s.1The2015reformsubstantiallyreduces
malapportionmentamongChamberdistricts,withMALdroppingfrom.17to.11,butthe
ChileanChamberremainsamongthemostmalapportionedlowerchambersintheworld.
Senatemalapportionment,moreover,atMAL=.32,isunchangedbythe2015reform.
Figure1plotsdistrictmagnitude(DM)againstpopulationforthetwenty-eightnewChamber
districts(toppanel)andfifteennewSenatedistricts(bottompanel).Notethat,intheChamber,
therearemanydistrictswithhigherpopulationsbutfewerseatsthancorrespondingdistricts
withfewerpeopleandmoreseats(anydotbelowandtotherightofanyother).Itispossibleto
havesubstantialmalapportionmentevenwithoutsuchinversions,buttheirexistenceis
particularlystriking.2
1Post-reformMALiscalculatedfromdataprovidedbytheObservatorioPoliticoElectoralatthe
UniversidadDiegoPortales,courtesyofPatricioNavia,withpopulationdatafromthemost
recent,2012nationalcensus.Pre-reformChamberMALiscalculatedfromdatadrawnfromthe
2002census,matchedtoChamberdistrictsonWikipedia
(http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Electoral_divisions_of_Chile).Pre-reformSenateMALis
calculatedbasedontotalvotersperdistrictratherthanpopulation,byaggregatingupthetotal
votescastineachSenatedistrictfromthe2001and2005electionsasaproxyfortherelative
districtpopulations.
2Forexample,usingthed'Hondtformulaofsuccessivedivisorstoapportionthe155seats
acrossthenewdistrictsbypopulationwouldretainMAL=.03,muchmoreinlinewithlower
chambersinmostdemocraciesworldwide,butwithnoseat-populationinversions(dataand
figureavailablefromauthor).
3
Figure1.Seatsbypopulation,post-reformChileanChamberandSenate
Despitethefactthatthe2015reformincreasedthenumberofSenateseats,reducedthe
numberofdistricts,andsoincreasedthemagnitudeofmanydistricts,theChileanupperhouse
willbeasmalapportionedasitwasbeforethereform,andslightlymoremalapportionedthanit
initiallywasthe1990s.Therearenocasesofmorepopulateddistrictsbeinggivenfewerseats
thanlesspopulatedones,asintheChamber,buttheSantiagoMetroregion'snearly7million
inhabitantsaredramaticallyunderrepresentedwithonlyfivesenators,thesamenumberasthe
TalcaorTemucoregions,eachwithapopulationunder1million.Evenmaintainingthecurrent
minimumoftwoseatsforeachnewdistrict,malapportionmentcouldbedramaticallyreduced
byredistributingseatsfromthemid-sizeddistrictstotheSantiagoMetroregion,withtheeffect
ofmorethandoublingthecapital'sseattotaloffive.3
Measuringdistrictideology
Todeterminewhethertheapportionmentofseatsconfersideologicaladvantage,Ineeda
measureofvoterpreferencesatthedistrictlevel.Legislativeelectionresultshavebeen
3Usingapured'Hondtformulatoapportionseatsinthepost-reformSenatewouldnotbe
feasibleasthedistrictsarecurrentlyconfigured,aseachoftheleastpopulatedfourdistricts
wouldwarrantnorepresentationatall.
4
systematicallyimperfectmetricsofdistrictpartisanpreferencesduringthebinominalera
becausethemajorcoalitionsallocatedtheirtwonominationswithineachdistrictinnegotiations
thatinvolvedtheirmultiplecomponentparties,withpartiesforfeitingtherighttonominatein
somedistrictsinexchangeforfavorableslotsinothers(Carey&Siavelis2005).Ratherthanuse
legislativeelectionresults,then,Irelyondatafrompresidentialcontestsandfrommunicipal
electionstomeasuredistrict-levelideology.
Forthispurpose,anyChileanelectionshavepotentialadvantagesanddisadvantages.Municipal
electionsimposethefewestconstraintsonvotersbecausedistrictmagnitudesarehigherfor
municipalcouncils,reducingtheimperativeforalliancestorationnominationsorforvotersto
votestrategically.Butmunicipalelectionsmayturnonlocalissues.Presidentialelections
embodythenationalleft-rightdivide,butthecontestforasingleofficemaximizedstrategic
constraintsonvoterchoice.Fortunately,theresultsofthisanalysisdonothingeonwhich
electionsweexamine.Imeasuredistrictideologythreedifferentways,basedon:
• second-roundpresidentialelections,codingvotesaseitherleftorright;
• municipalelections,codingpartiesasleftorrightaccordingtotheirparticipationin
nationalalliances;and
• municipalelections,codingpartiesaccordingtotheirideologyscoresfromBaker&
Greene's(2011)seminalarticleanddatabase,andcalculatingaweighteddistrict
ideologyscore.
Intheinterestofsimplicity,Ipresenttheresultsfrompresidentialelectionshere,butthe
analogousresultsusingbothmunicipalelection-basedmeasures,aswellasalternativemodel
specifications,areavailableinaweb-basedappendix.
IbeginwiththefourChileanpresidentialconteststhatproceededtoasecondroundpittinga
singlecandidatefromthecenter-leftagainstonefromthecenter-right.Becauseminor
candidates,whocansplitthevoteoneortheothersideofthespectrumduringafirst-round
electionhavebeeneliminated,therun-offelectionsprovideasimpleandcleanmeasureof
districtpreferencesbetweenleftandright.Fourpresidentialelectionsresultedinrun-offs,
listedbelowwiththeleftistcandidatesfirstandthewinningcandidateitalicized:
• January2000–RicardoLagos(PartyforDemocracy)vs.JoaquinLavin(Democratic
IndependentUnion)
• January2006–MichelleBachelet(Socialist)vs.SebastianPinera(NationalRenovation)
• January2010–EduardoFrei(ChristianDemocrat)vs.SebastianPinera(National
Renovation)
• December2013–MichelleBachelet(Socialist)vs.EvelynMattei(Democratic
IndependentUnion)
Tomeasuredistrictideology,Ibeginwithdataonpresidentialvotesatthelevelofcomuna,the
smallestadministrativesub-unitinChile.4Votetalliesatthecomunalevelcanbeaggregatedup
tothelevelofthepre-reform,binominaldistricts,andthepost-reform,multi-memberdistricts
4
Thereare346comunas,groupedinto54provinces,whichthemselvesaregroupedinto15
regions.
5
forboththeChamberandtheSenate.Foreachpresidentialrun-offelection,Icalculatethevote
talliesforeachcandidateineachcomuna,usingdatafromtheChileanServicioElectoralwebsite
(ServicioElectoraldeChile2015a).ThenImatchthosedatawithotherdataonthecomposition
ofthepre-andpost-reformChamberandSenatedistrictstoaggregatetalliesfromthecomuna
leveluptothelevelofeachofthefourtypesofdistricts(ServicioElectoraldeChile2015b,
ObservatorioPolíticoElectoral2015;SenadodeChile2015).Itallyupallthevotescastineach
typeoflegislativeelectoraldistrictforallfourleftistcandidatesandallfourrightistcandidates
acrossthesetofrun-offelections,thencalculateatheoverallleftistvoteshareasasingle,
district-levelmeasureofideology.Tallyingacrosselectionsreducesthepotentialimpactof
election-specificidiosyncrasies(e.g.,thelocalappealofaspecificcandidate)thatmight
otherwisedistortthedistrict-levelestimate.Summariesofthedistrict-levelleftismstatistics
acrossthefourelections,threeofwhichwerewonbytheleftistcandidateandonebythe
rightist,areshowninTable2.
Table2.Leftistshareoftwo-partyvoteinpresidentialrun-offelections,2000-2013
ChamberDistricts
SenateDistricts
Binominal
Post-Reform
Binominal
Post-Reform
Median
.59
.57
.57
.58
Minimum
.31
.43
.50
.51
Maximum
.72
.65
.65
.65
Noevidenceofideologicalbias
Figure2plotsdistrictleftism,ontheY-axes,againsthowwellrepresentedthedistrictwasinthe
binominalChamber(toppanel)andSenate(bottompanel)basedonpopulationduringthe
2000s.Linearbest-fitlineswith95%confidenceintervalsareimposedonthescatters.5Districts
thatareover-representedrelativetopopulationarefurthertotheleftontheX-axes,andunderrepresenteddistricts(withgreaterpopulationperrepresentative)aretotheright.Thus,an
upward-slopinglinewouldindicatethatmalapportionmentproducesbiasinfavoroftheright,
andadownwardslopewouldindicatebiasinfavoroftheleft.
5Usingaloess,ratherthanalinearfunctiondoesnotaltertheresults(seeonlineappendix).
6
Figure2.LeftismbyapportionmentinthebinominalChamberandSenate
Thebest-fitlinesareflat.Basedontheelectionresultssince2000,thereisnoevidenceofany
correlationbetweentheideologicalpreferencesofvotersinthebinominaldistrictsandhow
over-orunder-representedthedistrictswereintheChamberorintheSenate.
Figure3showsanalogousscatterplotsforthepost-reformdistricts.Thereisaslightupward
slopetothebest-fitlineforthepost-reformChamber,suggestingamildpro-rightistbiasfrom
malapportionmentinthenewChamberdistricts,buttherelationshipisnotevencloseto
statisticallysignificant(p=.56inabivariateregression).FortheSenate,thebest-fitlineis,again,
completelyflat.NotethattheSantiagoMetroregioncontinuestostandoutforitssevere
under-representation.
7
Figure3.Leftismbyapportionmentinthepost-reformChamberandSenate
Conclusion
Chile'sold,binominalsystemwasoftendecriedasfavoringtheright.The2015electoralreform
eliminatedthemostcontroversialsourceofbias,theuniquesetofseatthresholdsinherentin
two-memberdistrictcompetition.Italsoreducedthesecondpotentialsourceofbias,
malapportionment,somewhat,althoughthelegislativepoliticsofreformpreventedits
eliminationentirelyandsubstantialmalapportionmentremainsinthepost-reformsystem.
Usinganewmeasureofdistrictideology,thisanalysisfindsnoevidencethatmalapportionment
producedideologicalbiasundertheoldsystem,noranyreasontoexpectitwillproducesuch
biasinthenewone.Theabsenceofideologicalbiasdoesnotnecessarilymean
malapportionmentisinnocuous.InbothchambersoftheChileanCongress,thepreferencesof
votersinsomedistrictsstillcarryfarmoreweightthanthepreferencesofvotersinother
8
districts.Nevertheless,theapportionmentsystemadoptedin2015doesnotappeartobe
stackedinfavorofeitherleftorright.Tosumup,theprincipleofvoteequality–or"one
person,onevote"–continuestobeviolatedinChileanlegislativeelections,butthereisno
evidencethatmalapportionmentwillskewelectoraloutcomesacrossdistrictsaccordingtotheir
ideologicalpredispositions.
9
References
Anonymous2015."Chile’s2015ElectoralReform:OriginsandPossibleConsequences."
ManuscriptsubmittedtoLatinAmericanPoliticsandSociety–authorshipnotknown.
AuthStewart,Pepe.2014."Lahoradelcambiodelsistemabinominal,"inAngelFlisfischF.,
editor,Electorasyelectors,movimientos,partidos.Santiago:FLACSO,Chile2014.
Baker,AndyandKennethF.Greene.2011."LatinAmerica'sleftmandate:Free-marketpolicies
andissuevotinginnewdemocracies."WorldPolitics63(1):43-77.
Carey,JohnM.2002.“PartiesandCoalitionsinChileinthe1990s.”LegislativePoliticsinLatin
America,ScottMorgensternandBenitoNacif,eds.NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress:
222-253.
Carey,JohnM.andPeterM.Siavelis.2005.“Insuranceforgoodlosersandthesurvivalof
Chile’sConcertacion.”LatinAmericanPoliticsandSociety47(2):1-22.
Carey,JohnM.2006.“Lasvirtudesdelsistemabinominal."Revistadecienciapolítica
(Santiago,Chile)26(1):226-235.
Fuentes,Claudio.1999."PartidosycoalicionesenChiledelos90:Entrepactosyproyectos."In
Elmodelochileno:Democraciaydesarrolloenlosnoventa,ed.P.DrakeandI.Jaksic.
Santiago:LOMEdiciones.
Morales,Mauricio.2014."Haciaunsistemapoliticoexcesivamentepermisivo."Documentode
TrabajoICSO-No.11/2014,ObservatorioPolíticoElectoral,UniversidadDiegoPortales,
(Santiago,Chile).
Navia,Patricio.2005."Latransformacióndevotosenescaños:leyeselectoralesenChile,18332004."PolíticayGobiernoXII(2):233-76.
ObservatorioPolíticoElectoral.2015.UniversidadDiegoPortales,(Santiago,Chile).
Polga-Hecimovich,JohnandPeterSiavelis.Forthcoming.Here’stheBias!A(Re-)Reassessment
oftheChileanElectoralSystem."ElectoralStudies.
Rae, Douglas W. 1967. The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws. New Haven, CT: Yale
UniversityPress.Rojas,Priscilla,andPatricioNavia.2005."Representaciónytamañode
losdistritoselectoralesenChile,1988-2002."RevistadeCienciaPolítica25(2):91-116.
Samuels, David and Richard Snyder. 2001. "The value of a vote: Malapportionment in
comparativeperspective."BritishJournalofPoliticalScience31:651-671.
Scully,TimothyR.1997."ReconstitutingpartypoliticsinChile,"inPresidentialismand
DemocracyinLatinAmerica,ScottP.MainwaringandMatthewSobergShugart,eds.New
York:CambridgeUniversityPress.
Scully,TimothyR.,andJ.SamuelValenzuela.1997."Electoralchoicesandthepartysystemin
Chile:Continuitiesandchangesattherecoveryofdemocracy."ComparativePolitics
29(4):511-27.
SenadodelaRepublicadeChile.2015."Senadoresporregions."
(http://www.senado.cl/appsenado/templates/senadores/regiones.html)
ServicioElectoraldeChile.2015a."EleccionesPresidenciales1989al2013porCircunscripción
Electoral"(http://www.servel.cl/ss/site/resultadoselectorales.html)
ServicioElectoraldeChile.2015b.ResultadosenExcelporMesa(apartirdelaño2012).
(http://www.servel.cl/ss/site/resultadoselectorales.html)
10
ServicioElectoraldeChile.2015c."EleccionesMunicipales1992al2012porCircunscripcion
Electoral"(http://www.servel.cl/ss/site/resultadoselectorales.html)
Siavelis,Peter.1997."ContinuityandChangeintheChileanPartySystem:Onthe
TransformationalEffectsofElectoralReform."ComparativePoliticalStudies30(6):651-74.
Siavelis, Peter. 2000. The President and Congress in Post-Authoritarian Chile: Insitutional
Constraints to Democratic Consolidation. University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State
UniversityPress.
Siavelis,Peter.2002."TheHiddenLogicofCandidateSelectionforChileanParliamentary
Elections."ComparativePolitics:419-38.
Wikipedia.2015."ElectoraldivisionsofChile."
(http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Electoral_divisions_of_Chile,accessedonMay18,2015).
ZapataLarrain,Patricio."Elsistemabinominalysusefectossobrelademocracia
representative,"inAngelFlisfischF.,editor,Electorasyelectors,movimientos,partidos.
Santiago:FLACSO,Chile2014.
Zucco,Cesar,Jr.2007."Where'sthebias?AreassessmentoftheChileanelectoralsystem."
ElectoralStudies26(2):303-314.
11