restructuring, privatization, liberalization
Transcription
restructuring, privatization, liberalization
center for energy petroleum and mineral law and policy RESTRUCTURING, PRIVATIZATION, LIBERALIZATION AND REGULATORY REFORM OF TURKISH ELECTRICITY INDUSTRY INTELLECTUAL/ACADEMIC REPORT AUTHOR: CUNEYT BODUR∗ SUPERVISOR: MR. STEPHEN DOW Telif Hakkı Uyarısı: Bu akademik çalışmanın tüm hakları yazarı Avukat Cüneyt Bodur'e aittir ve yazarı tarafından Türk Hukuk Sitesi (http://www. turkhukuksitesi.com) kütüphanesinde yayınlanmış olup, başka bir yerde yayınlanması kesinlikle yasaktır. Bilgilendirme Yazısı: Yüksek Lisans tezi olarak hazırlanmış bu çalışmanın ardından Türkiye Elektrik sektöründen elbette bir takım değişiklikler meydana gelmiştir. Eser sektördeki liberalleşme ve özelleşme ile ilgili hala geçerli olan temel bilgiler vermekte ve ülkemizdeki süreçten bahsetmektedir. Bu eserin 13. sayfasındaki üretim oranları bugün itibariyle farklıdır. Sayfa 23 ve 24 yer alan dağıtım bölgeleri ve şehirlerin bazılarında da değişiklikler olmuştur. Bu hususların dışında, eserde sözü edilen sorunlardan büyük çoğunluğu maalesef ki bugün itibariyle de devam etmektedir. İlgililerine yardımcı olması dileklerimle. ***** Copy Right Warning: this present paper is submitted to Türk Hukuk Sitesi (http://www.turkhukuksitesi.com) by its author Cuneyt Bodur, and this present web-site is the only one granted with the permission to publish the paper. Any and all kinds of publishing on other web-sites are prohibited. Notification: Turkish Electricity sector has been evolved since the preparation of this present master degree report. However, all information regarding liberalization and privatization of the sector in Turkey is still alive and basic information on the history and the development of the sector is - of course - still accurate. But, please be kindly informed that the proportionate of generation on page 13 is now different, also some of the cities as well as the distribution areas(page 23 and 24) slightly different now. it is also pity that some of the problems mentioned in the paper such as competition issue in Turkey is yet to be completely solved. i wish the paper would be great help to those who are in need of knowledge on the issue. INDEX ABBREVIATIONS 1. INTRODUCTION ..………………………………………………………………….…... 1 2. HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENTS OF TURKISH ELECTRICITY INDUSTRY ..... 2 2.1. Early Ages (1902 – 1980) ……………………………………………………...... 2 2.2. Investment Models/Private Participation Models (1980 – 2000) ……………….. 4 2.2.1. Private Participation Models Used in This Term ……………………..... 5 2.2.1.1. Build-Operate-Transfer (BOT) ………………………………. 5 2.2.1.2. Build-Operate (BO) …………………………..……………..... 5 2.2.1.3. Transfer of Operating Rights (TOR) …………………………. 5 2.2.1.4. Autoproduction (APr) ………………………………………... 6 2.2.2. Why Were Private Participations Models Used in This Term? ……...... 6 2.2.3. Another Important Development in This Term …………………….….. 6 2.2.4. Evaluation of this Term ………………………………………………... 7 2.2.5. The Structure of TEI before the EML (Graphic I) ……………………. 7 2.3. Restructuring Electricity Industry/Reform Period (2000 – Present) …………..… 8 2.3.1. Aim and Scope of the Electricity Market Law ………………………… 8 2.3.2. Reasons of the Reform ………………………………………………… 8 2.3.3. Unbundling the Monopoly …………………………………………….. 9 2.3.4. Unbundling the TEI from 1993 to 2004 (Graphic II) ………………... 10 3. WHAT DOES ELECTRICITY MARKET LAW CALL FOR? …………………….. 10 3.1. Restructuring …………………………………………………………………… 10 3.2. Market Design ………………………………………………………………….. 11 3.2.1. Generation and Wholesale ……………………………………………. 12 3.2.1.1. Proportions of Generation Groups (Graphic III) ………….. 13 3.2.2. Transmission ………………………………………………………….. 14 3.2.2.1. What Caused Putting BaSeRe into Force? …………………. 14 3.2.2.2. What Does BaSeRe Call For? ……………………………… 14 3.2.2.2.1. Balancing [Dengeleme] ………...…………….. 15 3.2.2.2.2. Settlement [Uzlaştırma] ………………………. 15 3.2.2.3. How does the BSS work? …………………………………... 15 3.2.2.4. How Are the PPMs Supposed To Be Dealt within the BSS? ...... 17 3.2.3. Distribution and Retail Sale …………………………………………... 17 3.3. Independent Regulatory Agency …...………………………………………….. 17 3.4. New Structure of TEI after EML and SP (Graphic IV) ………………………... 19 4. PRIVATIZATION ……………………………………………………………………… 20 4.1. Privatization and Main Principles ……………………………………………… 20 4.2. Distribution Regions …………………………………………………………… 22 4.2.1. Defining DisRes ……………………………………………………… 22 4.2.2. DisRes of Turkey (Graphic V) ……………………………………….. 24 4.3. An Important Development Affecting DisRes …………………………………. 25 4.4. Why Did the Distribution Take First Place in Privatization? …………………... 25 4.5. How Will the DisCos be Privatized? …………………………………………… 25 4.5.1. Why Has TOR Been Chosen? ………………………………………... 25 4.5.2. The Steps to be Taken During the Privatization Process …………….. 26 4.6. Technical Lose and Theft Problems ……………………………………………. 28 4.7. Tariff Regulations ……………………………………………………………… 29 5. COMPETITION ………………………………………………………………………... 30 5.1. Which Will Prevail, EML or SP? ………………………………………………. 30 5.2. Law 5893 and Vertical Integration ……………………………………………... 31 6. CONCLUSION ………………………………………………………………………….. 33 7. ANNEX – 1 ……………………………………………………………………………… 35 8. BIBLIOGRAPHY ………………………………………………………………………. 36 ABBREVATIONS APr Autoproduction BaSeRe Electricity Market Balancing and Settlement Regulation BO Build-Operate BOT Build-Operate-Transfer BSP(s) Balancing System Participant(s) BSS Balancing and Settlement System CoM Council of Ministers CoS Council of State [Supreme Court of Administrative Courts] DisCo(s) Distribution Company(ies) DisRe(s) Distribution Region(s) EML Electricity Market Law EMRA Energy Market Regulatory Authority EU European Union EUAS Electricity Generation Co. GenCo(s) Generation Company(ies) HEPP Hydroelectric Power Plant HPC High Planning Council IMF International Monetary Fund MENR Ministry of Energy and Natural Resources MFSC Market Financial Settlement Center MP(s) Market Participant(s) NLDC National Load Dispatch Center OIZ Organized Industrial Zones PA Privatization Administration PEM Price Equalization Mechanism PPA Power Purchase Agreement PPMs "Private Participation Models" implies BOT, BO, TOR, and APr models together RetCo(s) Retail Company(ies) SHW State Hydraulic Works SP Electricity Sector Reform and Privatization Strategy Paper TCA Turkish Competition Authority TEAS Turkish Electricity Generation Transmission Co. TEDAS Turkish Electricity Distribution Co. TEI Turkish Electricity Industry TEIAS Turkish Electricity Transmission Co. TEK Turkish Electricity Institution TETAS Turkish Electricity Trading and Contracting Co. TOR Transfer of Operating Rights WB World Bank 1. INTRODUCTION In the 1990s, there was a worldwide push towards reforming the utility industries and monopolistic business structures, most notably in the electricity industry. The main aim of the reforms was to improve economic efficiency. The means by which this was to be achieved was the introduction of competition. 1 To create a competitive electricity market, where not existed before, requires any country to implement a wide range of structural and regulatory reforms. 2 Until the end of the twentieth century, few countries questioned the economic efficiency of state-owned and vertically integrated utilities and their role as monopoly service providers in the electricity industry. In 1990 the UK opted to move to a new industry structure involving full competition in generation and retail segments. This was achieved by unbundling the industry structure and making transmission and distribution common carriers. 3 On the other hand, Republic of Turkey (Turkey), with a young and growing population, low per capita electricity consumption, rapid urbanization and generally strong economic growth, for nearly two decades has been one of the fastest growing power markets in the world. The government anticipates the need for significant increases in power generating capacity in coming years, possibly 54,000 MW by 2020, requiring billions of dollars investment. 4 As insufficiency of public funds and poor performance of public electricity monopoly taken into consideration as well as the advices given from international institutions such as World Bank (WB) and International Monetary Fund (IMF), Turkey passed the long-anticipated Electricity Market Law (EML) 5 , in 2001, which envisages the establishment of a competitive electricity market and to promote private participation in the industry. 1 2 3 4 5 Pritchard, R., Eight Guidelines of Electricity Industry Reform, Vol. 12-7 Article. Online Journal CEPMLP (August 2002) at www.dundee.ac.uk/cepmlp/journal/html/volume12.php (last visited on 10 August 2006). Id. Pritchard, R., Andrews-Speed, P., Eight Principles of Electricity Industry Reform, Vol. 7-2 Article. Online Journal CEPMLP (July 2000) www.dundee.ac.uk/cepmlp/journal/html/volume7.php (last visited on 10 August 2006). International Energy Agency, Turkey Country Analysis Brief (June 2005), at www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/cabs/ turkey.html (last visited on 7 August 2006). Turkish Electricity Market Law, Law No. 4628, (entered into force March 2001). 1 This present paper examines regulatory reform, privatization and liberalization of the Turkish Electricity Industry (TEI). It firstly delivers information about the historical development of TEI and the investment models used therein, then mentions the reform process which includes restructuring the industry, new market design and privatization of distribution segments as well as the general competition issues arising from the liberalization of the industry. All these issues are examined within the frame of deductive methodology. The paper concludes that even Turkey has moved forward a lot since the enactment of EML, Turkey has still a long way to take and lots to learn due to there are still important issues waiting to be addressed or to be settled between concerned state and private parties of the process. 2. HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENTS OF TURKISH ELECTRICITY INDUSTRY 2.1. Early Ages (1902 – 1980) In Ottoman Empire, the first electric generator was a 2 kW dynamo connected to the water mill installed in Tarsus in 1902. This enterprise belonged to a private sector participant. 6 Electricity energy activities had been operated by foreigners in Ottoman Empire by way of obtaining respective concessions. 7 Electrification of Istanbul, for the first time, had been conducted by Macar Ganz Corp. on 1st of October 1910. This company was authorized on electricity generation and sales. 8 The first bigger power plant was installed in Silahtarağa region of Istanbul, in 1913. 9 Turkey was founded on 29th of October 1923 as a successor country of Ottoman Empire. Turkey was trying a liberal economy between 1923 and 1930s and the electricity sector was heavily dependent on foreign investment, mostly German, Belgium, Italian and Hungarian Companies. 10 The first Turkish electricity company, Kayseri ve Civarı 6 Hepbaslı, A., Development and Restructuring of Turkey’s Electricity Sector: a Review, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 9 (2005), at 311-343. See Also, Kulali, I., Electricity Sector and Privatization studies in Turkey, at http://ekutup.dpt.gov.tr/kit/kulalii/elektrik.html (last visited on 7 August 2006) in Turkish. 7 State Auditing Agency, Research Report With Respect to applications of BOT and TOR, at www.tccb.gov. tr/tr_html/DDK/enerji.htm (last visited on 07 August 2006) in Turkish. 8 BEDAS, History of Electricity in Istanbul, at http://www.bedas.gov.tr/bedas/tarihce.php (last visited on 07 August 2006) in Turkish. 9 See, Supra n6 10 Id. 2 Electricity Corp., was established in 1926. At the end of this era, there were 48 power plants (74.8 MW). 11 In 1930s, there was a widespread belief all over the world in the benefits of public ownership of the electricity industry. 12 Following to this trend “Statism” policies dominated the Turkish economy. Hence, all activities and companies in Electricity industry, except Kayseri ve Civarı Electricity Corp., were nationalized in 1938 as per the provisions of Law 3480. 13 This was followed by a legislation that allowed the municipals to build and operate power plants. In 1935, Etibank, Mineral Research and Exploration Institution, and Electrical Power Resources Survey Administration were founded, later the Bank of Provinces [İller Bankası] and State Hydraulic Works (SHW) [Devlet Su İşleri] were established. The installed capacity had reached 126.2 MW by 1950. 14 There was a diffused and de-centralized structure in this period of TEI. 15 In 1953, 1st Energy Consultation Congress [1. Enerji İstişare Kongresi] was conducted for the purpose of preventing diffusing and providing a centralized structure to industry. The two most important decisions taken in this congress were; 9 To build big and powerful hydraulic and thermal power stations in lieu of small and local diesel stations. 9 To transfer electrification activities carried out by various institutions to one central and state owned electricity institution. 16 In 1960, the government started the “development plans era” which was more of a national policy than a global one. The Ministry of Energy and Natural Resources (MENR) [Enerji ve Tabii Kaynaklar Bakanlığı] was established in December 1963, and was responsible of Turkey’s energy policy. 17 This was followed by the creation of Turkish Electricity Institution (TEK) [Türkiye Elektrik Kurumu] by Law 1312 on 15th July 1970 (barely, 17 11 Id. Erdogdu, E., Regulatory Reform in Turkish Energy Industry: An analysis, Energy Policy Journal, article in press, at doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2006.02.011 (last visited on 07 August 2006). 13 See, Supra n8 14 See, Supra n6 15 See, Supra n7 16 Id. 17 See, Supra n6 12 3 years later than the 1st Energy Consultation Congress). 18 TEK had a monopoly in Turkish electricity sector at almost all stages apart from distribution, which was left to the local administrations such as municipalities and the Bank of Provinces. However, distribution was also transferred to TEK as per provisions of Law 2705 in 1982, thus TEK became a vertically integrated, state-owned monopoly. 19 The only exemption in these transfer transactions was hydroelectric generators, which had been constructed and operated by Directorate General of SHW. 20 Installed capacity reached 2,234.9 MW by 1980. 21 2.2. Investment Models/Private Participation Models (1980 – 2000) In the early of 1980’s, like many European countries, TEI was dominated by a vertically integrated and state-owned monopoly. Starting from 1980s, Turkey sought to attract private participation into the industry. 22 The reasons behind this disposition can be summarized as fallows; 9 In 1980, Turgut Özal who was a liberal economy supporter won the elections, became the Prime Minister and initiated his liberalization policies. 9 Insufficiency of public funds, 9 Poor performance of public electricity monopoly 23 9 Improve the efficiency of electricity sector. 9 Rapid urbanization, young population, and growing electricity consumption 18 See, Supra n7 See, Supra n12 20 Ozkıvrak, O., Electricity Restructuring in Turkey, Energy Policy Journal 33 (2005), at 1339-1350. 21 See, Supra n6 22 Bodur, C., Regulatory Framework of Build-Operate-Transfer Model in Turkey, presented Research Paper for International Project Finance course at CEPMLP, April 2006. 23 In 2000, the losses of TEAS reached 656 million USD (See, Supra n20). This amount derived from the unpaid amount of the electricity that bought by TEDAŞ. TEDAS was not able to pay the price of the electricity due to it had difficulty in collecting fees from, particularly, public utilities such as municipalities. Even, as of 2006 this amount is decreasing, there is important problem in terms of revenue stream between state-owned institutions. Source: www.ntvmsnbc.com/news/382356.asp (last visited at 07 August 2006) in Turkish. 19 4 2.2.1. Private Participation Models Used in This Term 2.2.1.1. Build-Operate-Transfer (BOT) The first codification with respect to BOT was made in energy sector in 1984. The Law 3096 changed the monopolistic structure of TEK and provided scope to private sector – for the first time since 1930s – to conduct commercial activities in generation, transmission, distribution and trade of electrical energy. 24 Four Bylaws were later issued to clarify the application of this law. Here are the associated Bylaws; 85/9759, 85/9800, 87/11488, and 91/1630. In 1990s financial strains also increased for public infrastructure investments due to lack of funds. Therefore, there was a need of a codification which would regulate (unify) BOT models in every sector in economy, a general BOT law. Consequently, Law 3996 which regulates BOT model as general was enacted in 13th of June 1994. Afterwards, Bylaw 94/5907 was published on October 1994 to clarify the application of this law. 25 2.2.1.2. Build-Operate (BO) Law 4283, for private sector participation in construction and operation of new power plants was also enacted in 1997 and treasury guarantees provided as it had happened in BOT model. 26 Bylaw 97/9853 was later issued to clarify the application of this law. 2.2.1.3. Transfer of Operating Rights (TOR) Law 3096 also covered Transfer of Operating Rights (TOR) of existing power plants and transmission and distribution facilities owned by the state (article 5) to the private enterprises. 27 Council of Ministers (CoM) [Bakanlar Kurulu] had authority on TOR as per the provisions of Bylaw 87/11488. 24 See, Supra n22 See, Supra n22 26 See, Supra n12 27 See, Supra n22 25 5 2.2.1.4. Autoproduction (APr) In 1984, following the enactment of Law 3096, autoproduction in Turkey picked up at a fast pace. “Autoproducers” are those entities that essentially generate electricity for their own and their shareholders’ use. The major underlying reason for the fast spread of autoproduction is no doubt reliability and cost concerns of the industrial sector. Increased thermal efficiency in cogeneration technologies and the possibility of selling surplus energy to the national grid continues to make these investments more attractive. Currently, industrial plants with cogeneration units can achieve savings of up to 50 percent on their energy bills as compared to the cost of grid power in Turkey. 28 2.2.2. Why Were Private Participation Models Used in This Term? First of all, Turkey didn’t have any idea of privatization of electricity industry due to electricity industry reform, or opening the industry into competition, was not as widely spread all over the world as it is now. Secondly, the main reason why Turkey opted to try to attract private investment to the sector which was regarded as a “public service” was insufficiency of public funds. Also, had Turkey intended to privatize the electricity, it would have faced with enormous legal problems due to electricity had been deemed as “Public Service” that had to be carried out by state under the Turkish Constitution. One of the exemptions to this maxim was concession. Hence, Turkey tried to use the concession methods to realize those capital intensive investments. 2.2.3. Another Important Development in This Term In 1993, TEK was split into two separate state institutions: Turkish Electricity Generation Transmission Co. (TEAS) and Turkish Electricity Distribution Co. (TEDAS) by the Decree of CoM (Dec. no: 93/4789). The reasoning of this Decree was to provide more 28 Directly taken from the work: Serhat Guney, E., Restructuring, Competition, and Regulation in the Turkish Electricity Industry (Istanbul: Turkey, Tepav Publication, 2005). 6 efficient and more effective services to industry and to incorporate TEK into privatization plan. 29 2.2.4. Evaluation of This Term BOT, BO, and TOR contracts which were concluded between private sector participants and the administration (TEAŞ and TEDAŞ), stipulated “take or pay” obligations with fixed quantities (in general, 85% of plants’ output). 30 Under these models, the government retains most commercial risks. In Turkish case; there was no requirement for a competitive tender process, particularly as per Law 3096, to conclude these contracts which resulted, for sure, in high electricity prices. 31 Most of the commentators criticize these Private Participation Models (PPMs) and regard them as major barriers to development of the competitive electricity sector due to there are some privileged companies who have hedge and don’t bear the commercial risk, whereas all participants are to be equal in any market asserting to be a competitive one. 2.2.5. Structure of TEI before the EML (Graphic I) The below given graphic is taken from the article “The Politics of Regulation in the Turkish Electricity Market” 32 and modified by the author. 29 Turkish Electricity Distribution Co. (official web site), History of the Institution, at http://www.tedas.gov. tr/1,Hakkimizda.html (last visited on 07 August 2006) in Turkish. 30 See, Supra n7 31 See, Supra n12 32 Cetin, T., Oguz, F., The Politics of Regulation in the Turkish Electricity Market, Energy Policy Journal, article in press, at doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2006.05.014 (last visited on 07 August 2006). 7 2.3. Restructuring Electricity Industry/Reform Period (2000 – Present) 2.3.1. Aim and Scope of Electricity Market Law Turkish Electricity Market Law (EML), Law 4628, was enacted in 2001. The main objective of Law, as stated in Article 1, is “to ensure the development of a financially stable and transparent electricity market operating in a competitive environment under provisions of civil law and the delivery of sufficient, good quality, low cost and environment-friendly electricity to consumers and to ensure the autonomous regulation and supervision of this market.” 33 This law covers generation, transmission, distribution, wholesale, retail and related services of electricity; rights and responsibilities of all real persons and legal entities involved with those activities and establishment of a independent regulatory authority and determination of operating principles of this authority; and the methods to be employed for privatization of electricity generation and distribution assets. 34 2.3.2. Reasons of the Reform The reasons and/or problems (in addition to the ones mentioned in section 2.2.) that initiated the reform process in TEI can be summarized as fallows; 9 The MENR has planned for a very large increase in electric generating capacity over the next 20 years. According to forecasts prepared by the MENR, the country will need about an electric power capacity of 65 GW by 2010, and about 105 GW by 2020. Electric energy generation capacity is expected to have to rise from about 117 TW h in 2001 to more than 347 and 624 TW h in 2010 and 2020, respectively. This implies power demand growth rates of at least 8% per annum 35 for the coming decade and at least 6% per annum for the following decade. 36 33 Article 1 of EML Article 1/paragraph II of EML 35 Indeed electricity consumption increased 8.46 % in Turkey this year. Source: www.enerjiforumu.com/ gazete/?ID=2050 (last visited on 25 August 2006) in Turkish. 36 See, Supra n6 34 8 9 Decreasing the technical losses in distribution segment to the level in OECD countries and prevention of theft (illegal use of electricity) 37 . 9 Realization of reform has been underlined by the international financial institutions such as IMF and WB that have supported Turkey through the economic crises under Stand-by arrangements, 38 9 Reform has also paralleled the Turkey’s longer term objectives of accession into European Union (EU) and has needed to approximate laws to EU acquis, consequently which requires progressive liberalization of electricity market. 39 9 Transferring to consumers the benefits obtained through competition in generation, trade of electricity, and regulation of quality of service. 40 2.3.3. Unbundling the Monopoly To satisfy the provisions of EML, TEAS was unbundled, by Decree of CoM (Dec. no 2001/2026 dated 5th of February 2001), into three state-owned public enterprises, namely Electricity Generation Co. (EUAS), Turkish Electricity Transmission Co. (TEIAS), and Turkish Electricity Trading and Contracting Co. (TETAS). 41 37 High Planning Council, Electricity Sector Reform and Privatization Strategy, at www.oib.gov.tr/program/ 2004_program/2004_electricity_strategy_paper.htm (last visited on 7 August 2006). 38 See, Supra n20 39 Id. 40 See, Supra n37 41 Turkish Electricity Trading and Contracting Co. (official web site), at www.tetas.gov.tr/tanitimson.htm (last visited on 7 August 2006) in Turkish. 9 2.3.4. Unbundling the TEI from 1993 to 2004 (Graphic II) Illustration is made by the author and the graphic artist, Nurettin Gumusbas. 3. WHAT DOES ELECTRICITY MARKET LAW CALL FOR? EML was designed to establish a competitive electricity market, to promote private participation and improve efficiency in industry. 42 The key features of EML are as fallows; 3.1. Restructuring As explained above, TEAS has been further unbundled into EUAS (generation), TETAS (wholesale) and TEIAS (transmission). Each of them has been formed as a separate stateowned legal entity. 42 See, Supra n20 10 Under the new structure; 9 EUAS takes over existing public power plants that have not been transferred to private sector. 43 Same article also stipulates EUAS to take over the Hydroelectric Power Plants (HEPP) which are currently under the possession of SHW. According to the studies conducted by SHW, EUAS and Advisory of State Treasury, 9 billion USD has been defined for transferring 31 HEPP to EUAS. 44 9 TETAS is formed to carry out wholesale operations and it seems that it will dominate wholesale market in the near future 45 , because the privatization in generation segment will be conducted after successful privatization of distribution segment. 46 TETAS, also becomes the holder of all previously concluded BO, BOT and TOR contracts, including long-term PPA with treasury guarantees, and will assume other stranded costs. 47 9 TEIAS is responsible for transmission which remains under the ownership of state and also has the capacity of “System Operator” and “Market Operator” as well under the Electricity Market Balancing and Settlement Regulation. 9 TEDAS has been divided into 21 distribution region as per strategy paper issued by High Planning Council (HPC) [Yüksek Planlama Kurulu]. Further information regarding TEDAS is provided below in section 4.2. and ongoing sections. 3.2. Market Design At the heart of new structure, bilateral contracts 48 market where generation companies (GenCos) contract with wholesale trade companies, distribution companies (DisCos), retail companies (RetCos) and eligible consumers. The current market design does not envisage a pool or power exchange. The equality of demand and supply, given the bilateral contracts, is to be carried out by the System Operator (TEIAS) through purchases and sales 43 Article 2/a.1 of EML. Also See, Supra n37 Source: http://www.enerjiforumu.com/gazete/?ID=2047 (last visited on 24 August 2006) in Turkish. 45 See, Supra n12 46 See, Supra n37 47 See, Supra n12. Also, see Article 2/d.1 of EML 48 Bilateral contracts are the agreements whose terms and conditions are freely determined by parties and subject to private law. Source: Energy Market Regulatory Authority, Electricity Market Implementation Manual (April 2003), at http://www.epdk.org.tr/english/reports/electricity.htm (last visited on 7 August 2006). 44 11 in a balancing market. 49 In order to realize this task, National Load Dispatch Center has been established within TEIAS. 3.2.1. Generation and Wholesale The state has a controlling power in the generation by EUAS. The share of state-owned generators is % 45,40. 50 (The graphic displaying proportions among different generation groups added below as section 3.2.1.1.) In addition, according to the “existing contracts”51 the state through TETAS(wholesale company) have to purchase almost all electricity generated by the private companies involved in PPMs. 52 As explained earlier in this paper, these models were granted Treasury Guarantees, therefore TETAS has to buy and market the electricity generated by the above-mentioned models until the “existing contracts” expire. It seems that the dominant position of state in generation and its monopoly in wholesale will continue, at least, for the coming five years due to the “existing contracts”. Also, investors have not invested to industry due to, most probably, uncertainties on industry. Therefore, it is easy to conclude that the state will continue to be the determinative investor of the industry in near future. As it is stated by many scholars, existing contracts negatively affect new entrants because of privileged trading relationships and non-competitive pricing. The two main reasons behind high electricity prices generated by PPMs are, 9 They are mostly natural gas fired power plants. Hence, the initial investment cost respectively low but the cost of electricity generation is high as compared to other investment models such as HEPP, or lignite fired power plants, etc. 9 There was no requirement for prequalification or even for a competitive open tender process to conclude the contracts. They were mostly signed through a negotiation processes which the state was incompetent. 49 See, Supra n12 Energy Market Regulatory Authority (official web site), Annual Report (2005), at www.epdk.gov.tr/yayin_ rapor/yillik/yillik .htm (last visited on 7 August 2006). 51 Existing contracts are the contracts and concession agreements and implementation agreements concluded between the private companies and the government prior to enactment of EML 2001 in accordance with the investment models such as BOT, BO and TOR. (Article 1 of EML). 52 See, Supra n20 50 12 The method opted by Turkey to overcome this high electricity price is to blend low cost generation which includes HEPP generation with the PPMs’ electricity. This operation is conducted by TETAS. It purchases low cost electricity from state-owned generators and high cost electricity from private generators and blend them (in terms of their cost) and sells to market. In order to form a competitive wholesale market, TETAS is expected to loose its controlling power over the coming years particularly at the end of the term of these contracts. On the other hand, EML envisages some restrictions, in order to assure competition, on future private wholesale companies such as the related companies are to be legally restricted to a market share of 10% of the total electricity consumed in the market in preceding year. 53 Also some restrictions have been set out on private generation companies in order to prevent concentration which may lead to market power in the segment. E.g. total market share of a particular private generation company and its affiliates can not exceed 20% of the published figure of for the total installed capacity in Turkey in the preceding year. 54 3.2.1.1. Proportions of Generation Groups (Graphic III) The data used in this graphic were taken from EMRA’s 2005 Report. 55 Illustration is made by the author. 50,00% 45,40% 45,00% 40,00% 35,00% 30,00% 25,00% 20,00% 15,00% 10,00% 5,00% 25,80% 10,60% 8,50% 6,50% 2,50% 0,50% A .P r St at e G en er at BO or s & A Mo .P de r l G G r en BO ou p .L ic T M s en ce od el H ol d T M e ob OR rs i le M G o e n de er l at or s 0,00% 53 Article 2/d.2 of EML See, Supra n20 55 See, Supra n50 54 13 3.2.2. Transmission EML defines transmission as “the transport of electricity through lines higher than 36 kV”. 56 In the new structure, transmission remains under state ownership 57 . TEIAS takes over transmission assets, plans new transmission investments and build new transmission facilities. 58 It is known that, transmission system is principally governed by a central administration due to technical features of transmission rather than economic concerns. 59 Also, in the bilateral contracting model which adopted by Turkey, TEIAS has important roles in the market both as a “system operator” and a “market operator”. These tasks are to be carried out as per provisions of both EML and Electricity Market Balancing and Settlement Regulation 60 (BaSeRe) [Dengeleme ve Uzlaştırma Yönetmeliği]. Even this regulation was enacted in 2004, it was not in use as de facto until 1st of August 2006. Until this date, the system worked on fix prices for loading and de-loading of electricity. 3.2.2.1. What Caused Putting BaSeRe into Force? What caused putting BaSeRe into force is that Turkey has faced electricity interruption on 1st of July 2006 and 13 cities including third biggest city of Turkey, Izmir, buried into darkness at weekend. 61 This event triggered big debates about PPMs particularly about autoproducers who did not load electricity on the ground that they lose money due to low electricity prices and high cost such as natural gas price. Minister of Energy and Natural Resources, Mr. Hilmi Güler, stated that there is no shortage problem in Turkey (as of today, Turkey has over 15% additional generation capacity) but a tariff problem. 62 As a result of this development BaSeRe has been put into force on 1st of August 2006. 3.2.2.2. What Does BaSeRe Call For? BaSeRe envisages a “Balancing and Settlement System” (BSS). BSS is defined as a “system that consists of activities related with real-time balancing the demand and supply 56 Article 1/12 of EML Article 2/b, and Article 3/c.2 of EML 58 Article 2/b of EML 59 See, Supra n20 60 Official Gazette dated 03/11/2004, no 25632 61 Source: www.ntvmsnbc.com/news/381273.asp (last visited on 7 August 2006) in Turkish. 62 Source: http://www.zaman.com.tr/?bl=sondakika&alt=&trh=20060706&hn=301878 (last visited on 7 August 2006) in Turkish. 57 14 through acceptance of bids and offers, financial settlement of payables and receivables arising from energy supplied to or withdrawn from the system, parties engaged in these activities and relations among the parties” under the article 1 of BaSeRe. Minister Mr. Güler stated that balancing and settlement mechanism was the brain of the electricity system. There are two different tasks carried out by the BSS. Such as; 3.2.2.2.1. Balancing [Dengeleme] Balancing equalizes the system supply and demand of active electricity energy on real time. This task is carried out by the unit under the body of TEIAS named as “National Load Dispatch Center (NLDC) [Milli Yük Tevzii Merkezi]. 63 This center is also named (authorized) as “system operator”. 64 The aim of the Balancing is to ensure supply of sufficient and good quality energy with low-cost in a continuous manner. 3.2.2.2.2. Settlement [Uzlaştırma] Settlement calculates amounts payable or receivable by legal entities operating in the market, based on differences between actual purchases and sales as a result of the real time physical balancing of energy supply and demand by NLDC, in accordance with the provisions of the relevant legislation. This task is carried out by the unit under the body of TEIAS named as “Market Financial Settlement Center (MFSC) [Piyasa Mali Uzlaştırma Merkezi]. 65 This center is also named (authorized) as “market operator”. The aim of the Settlement is to establish financially sound, stable and transparent electricity market operating in a competitive environment under provisions of civil law. 3.2.2.3. How Does the BSS Work? First of all, we had better if we mention who the market participants (MP) and balancing system participants (BSP) are. Under article 10 of BaSeRe; MPs shall consist of licensed legal entities that supply energy to the system or withdrawn energy from the system 63 Article 4 of BaSeRe Article 14 of BaSeRe 65 Article 4 of BaSeRe 64 15 through participating in the balancing mechanism and/or their short and/or long energy positions. The market participants shall consist of the following: a) Generation licensees, b) Autoproducer licensees, c) Autoproducer group licensees, d) Wholesale licensees, e) Retail licensees. Under the article 12 of BaSeRe, BSP shall consist of licensees engaged in generation activity. A MP shall have at least one balancing system entity 66 registered to its name in order to be a BSP. Secondly, as we mentioned previously in this paper, EML envisages a bilateral contracting market design. Hence, MPs conclude agreements that subject to civil law, and MPs are obliged to notify MFSC about their sell and purchase agreements. This notification is vitally important not only in terms of Settlement but Balancing as well. Because, no matter how sensitive an estimate is made in the beginning, the supply-demand balance foreseen in the bilateral contract may be disrupted due to changing conditions and unforeseen situations concerning either side. 67 In this case, the system operator (NLDC) shall ensure the final physical balance by making giving orders to generators to load or de-load, based on bids and offers submitted by generators. The market operator (MFRC) charges market participants for the balancing and settlement costs they caused. 68 Until the balancing and settlement mechanism becomes fully operational, those bilateral contracts to which state-owned entities are a party will be subject to regulation, in order to enable market participants gain experience in carrying out bilateral contracts and ensure that they will not be subject to excessive extra costs arising from system imbalance.69 66 Balancing System Entity “Generation facility or part of the generation facility eligible to participate in the balancing mechanism.” (Article 4 of BaSeRe). 67 See, Supra n50 68 Id. 69 Id. 16 3.2.2.4. How Are the PPMs Supposed To Be Dealt within the BSS? Under the provisional article 1 of BaSeRe, The generation companies, that are currently selling electricity to TETAS within the framework of BO, BOT and TOR contracts, shall be registered with the MFSC by TETAS under TETAS account. TETAS shall bear all rights and liabilities arising from all transactions as indicated in this Regulation regarding submission of physical notifications, associated data and bids-offers for such balancing system entities and their participation in the balancing system. 70 3.2.3. Distribution and Retail Sale These issues are examined comprehensively below in Section 4 (Privatization). 3.3. Independent Regulatory Agency To ensure transparency and independent regulation over the sector, administratively independent and financially autonomous “Electricity Market Regulatory Authority” had been established as per EML and it was later renamed as “Energy Market Regulatory Authority” (EMRA) [Enerji Piyasası Düzenleme Kurumu] as per the provisions of Natural Gas Market Law no. 4646. With the enactment of the Petroleum Market Law no.5015 and Liquefied Petroleum Gas (LPG) Market Law no. 5307, the Authority has been commissioned to regulate and supervise the petroleum and LPG markets as well. Members of the Energy Market Regulatory Board assumed duty on November 19, 2001. 71 In the new structure, the state has an active role in transmission and in balancing and settlement mechanism. But, in the competitive segments, generation and trading of electricity, the state role and authority vested in EMRA. With the establishment of EMRA, the role of the MENR is focused on the establishment and enforcement of general energy policies, privatization proposals, determining import and export policies and the promotion of supply security. 72 70 Provisional Article 1 of BaSeRe EMRA (official web site), at www.epdk.gov.tr/english/default.asp (last visited on 7 August 2006). 72 See, Supra n20 71 17 The main functions of EMRA; 9 Granting Licenses and Determining Provisions Therein. 73 All participants engaging in electricity activities are required to obtain related licenses. The terms and conditions such as prices, cancellation, renewals and dispute settlements of these licenses are defined in detail by EMRA. 9 Approving Secondary Legislation. EMRA approves Grid Regulation, Distribution regulation, Customer Services Regulation, and BaSeRe. 74 9 Determining eligible customers over time. 75 Eligible consumers are any real person or legal entity that has the liberty to choose its supplier (may choose from a distribution, retail sale or wholesale company or directly from generation company), due to its consumption of more electricity than the amount defined by EMRA or its direct connection to the transmission system 76 (The limit for eligible consumers is defined as 6 million kW/h by EMRA on 25th of January 2006.) 77 On the other hand, non-eligible consumers have to purchase electricity from the distribution or the retail sale companies operating in that region at the price determined by EMRA. 9 Preparing Respective Tariffs. 78 Some of the tariffs that are prepared by EMRA are as follows; the connection and use of system tariff, transmission tariff, wholesale price tariff, distribution tariff, and retail tariff. 9 Overseeing the performance of market participants. 79 To oversee (audit) the activities and practices of legal entities operating in the market, as well as their compliance with the terms and conditions of their respective licenses, in order to ensure compliance with non-discrimination and transparency standards. 9 Protecting customer rights. 9 Imposing sanctions to parties that not complying with their obligations under applicable legislation or respective licenses. 80 73 Article 5 of EML Article 5/II.a of EML 75 Article 5/b of EML 76 Article 1 of EML 77 EMRA Decision dated 25/01/2006 (Decision no 641) in Turkish. 78 Article 13 of EML 79 Article 5/i of EML 80 Article 11 of EML 74 18 As it has mentioned earlier, EMRA has administrative and financial autonomy. It earns its revenues principally from licensing fees. Under current framework, any lawsuit against decision delivered by EMRA may be appealed to Council of State (CoS) [Danıştay]. 3.4. New Structure of TEI after EML and SP (Graphic IV) Even the below presented graphic is illustrated in accordance with the applicable legislation, it is under the copyright of the author and the graphic artist due to its distinctive design and configuration, also to the best of the author’s knowledge there are several graphics in literature which try to depict the structure, however they are not similar at all with the one given below. 19 4. PRIVATIZATION 4.1. Privatization and Main Principles EML envisages privatization both in generation and in distribution segments, and liberalization in every segment of the industry except transmission which remains under state ownership. Under the 14th article of EML, MENR notifies to the Privatization Administration (PA) [Özelleştirme İdaresi Başkanlığı] the proposals and opinions regarding the privatization of the assets belonging to the TEDAS, EUAS, and their subsidiaries, affiliates, partnerships and operational units and facilities. The privatization process is executed by the PA as per the provisions of Privatization Law 4046 81 . On 17th of March 2004, High Planning Council (HPC) 82 [Yüksek Planlama Kurulu] issued the Strategy Paper (SP) 83 regarding electricity industry reform and privatization. SP outlines the major steps to be taken in order to realize considered privatization. According to SP, privatization was supposed to start in distribution sector and all Distribution Regions (DisRes) were expected to be privatized until the end of 2006 84 . As of today, there is no DisRe privatized but at least one of them is to be opened to bids until the end of this year. Also some public procurement provisions which released to the newspapers are mentioned below. Under SP, the basic principles of Privatization are as follow; 85 9 The privatization activities will be performed by the PA within the framework of the provisions of Law 4046. This provision is exactly the same with the one in EML. 9 The privatization approach will not be solely aimed at the maximization of privatization income. Despite the fact of this principle, the privatization of Distribution will be realized without unbundling from Retail if any changes not made in days to come. 81 Enacted on 27 November 1994 and published in Official Gazette dated 27/11/1994. HPC is composed of Prime Minister, Ministers and Advisor of State Planning Organization. 83 HPC, Decree No: 2004/3, “Electricity Sector Reform and Privatization Strategy Paper”, See Supra n37 84 See, Supra n37 85 Taken from SP and comments added by the author. 82 20 9 There will be utmost efforts to ensure that the privatization does not lead to permanent increases in electricity prices. Hence, EMRA is to regulate the terms and conditions of transition term tariffs that will be in force after the first five years of privatization. 9 The participation of financially strong companies able to achieve the objectives and principles of the program will be encouraged in the privatization process. This principle is being criticized a lot by most of the commentators, particularly by the left wing supporters, due to this principle provide vital advantages to giant foreign companies such as RWE, E-ON etc. As we mentioned before, some provisions of public procurement which have been defined by PA have been released to public as of August 2006, such as 86 ; • Technical Sufficiency; 1) The Company has to be conducting power sales equivalent to aggregated amount of sold electricity in a year in that DisRe for at least 3 years in order to meet this provision. 2) The Company has to be carrying out distribution services, for at least three years, to the customers whose population equivalent or larger then the respective DisRe. • Capital Sufficiency; 1) Equity [Öz Sermaye] – Book Value [Defter Değeri] Ratio may be no less than 65% which means the bidder has to prove that its equity equals or excesses the 65% of Book Value of assets to be privatized. 2) Fixed Assets [Sabit Değerler] – Book Value Ratio may be no less than 50% which means the fixed assets of the bidder has to be equal to 50% of Book Value of the assets to be privatized. 9 A competitive generation structure will be achieved through appropriately grouping generation assets, like portfolio companies, (disaggregation) prior to their privatization. As of today, there are six portfolio generation companies whose installed capacities are almost equal to each other. This provision is also important in terms of introducing competition into generation segment of the industry. 9 The privatization approach will take into account existing public liabilities and will not lead to additional State guarantees. This provision can be regarded as the reflection of the provision of EML which prohibits granting treasury guarantees in TEI. 86 Source: http://www.enerjiforumu.com/gazete/?ID=2044 (last visited on 7 August 2006) in Turkish. 21 4.2. Distribution Regions 4.2.1. Defining DisRes As a consequent of EML and SP, TEDAS 87 have been taken into privatization portfolio of PA by the decision of Privatization High Council on 2nd of May 2004 88 . As we mentioned earlier in this paper, 21 DisRes have been defined within Turkey. Under SP the reason and the aim taken into consideration while defining the regions are; “with due regard to the operational problems as a result of the geographical structure, the size of the region as compared to energy purchased and technical/financial characteristics, the “existing contracts”, and the current legal process in Turkey, the number of distribution regions have been determined at most 21 throughout the country” 89 All DisRes, except Kayseri ve Civarı Electricity Corp. which continues to hold concession since the early ages of Turkey, are to be privatized. Before presenting the DisRes, we, here, want to mention that WB criticizes the number of DisRes. WB thinks the number of DisRes excessive. Here is the diagram of DisRes that encloses associated information. 9 DisRes’ numbers and names of provinces taken directly from the Turkish version of SP at page 8). 9 Aggregated technical lose and theft ratio of the regions and the names of DisCos also added to the below table by the author. • The technical lose and theft date used here taken from the Atıyas work 90 and belongs to 2004. They are provided as aggregated because the precise ratio of technical lose has not been determined. • DisCos’ names were taken from the document bears the opinion delivered by Turkish Competition Authority (TCA) [Rekabet Kurumu] on 21 July 2005. 87 Number of Employees; 31,950 (as of March 2005), Capital Share Holding: 1,050,000,000 New Turkish Liras (app. 384,000,000 GBP). Source: Privatization Administration (official web site), at www.oib.gov.tr/ portfoy/tedas_eng.htm (last visited on 22 August 2006). 88 Privatization High Council (Decree No: 2004/22) in Turkish. 89 See, Supra n37 90 Atiyas, I., Liberalization and Regulatory Reform in Electricity Sector, (Istanbul: Turkey, TESEV Publications, 2006) in Turkish. 22 Num. Of DisRe Name of DisCo Associated Provinces Agg.'ed Ratio 1 Dicle Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş. Diyarbakır, Mardin, Siirt, Şanlıurfa, Batman, Şırnak 62,6 2 Vangölü Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Bitlis, Hakkâri, Muş, Van 61,2 3 Aras Elektrik A.Ş Ağrı, Erzincan, Erzurum, Kars, Bayburt, Ardahan, Iğdır 33,5 4 Çoruh Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Artvin, Giresun, Gümüşhane, Rize, Trabzon 13,4 5 Fırat Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Bingöl, Elazığ, Malatya, Tunceli 15,3 6 Çamlıbel Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Sivas, Tokat, Yozgat 11,0 7 Toroslar Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Adana, Mersin, Osmaniye, Hatay, Gaziantep, Kilis 16,5 8 Meram Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Kırşehir, Nevşehir, Niğde, Aksaray, Konya, Karaman 8,7 9 Başkent Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Ankara, Kırıkkale, Zonguldak, Bartın, Karabük, Çankırı, Kastamonu 9,4 10 Akdeniz Elektrik A.Ş Antalya, Burdur, Isparta 11 Gediz Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş İzmir, Manisa 7,5 12 Uludağ Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Balıkesir, Bursa, Çanakkale, Yalova 7,1 13 Trakya Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Edirne, Kırklareli, Tekirdağ 10,8 14 İstanbul Anadolu Yakası Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş İstanbul – Asia Part 10,5 15 Sakarya Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Sakarya, Bolu, Düzce, Kocaeli 13,9 16 Osmangazi Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Afyon, Bilecik, Eskişehir, Kütahya, Uşak 17 Boğaziçi Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş İstanbul – European Part 18 Kayseri ve Civarı Elektrik T.A.Ş Kayseri 19 Menderes Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Aydın, Denizli, Muğla 20 Göksu Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Adıyaman, Kahramanmaraş 12,2 21 Yeşilırmak Elektrik Dağıtım A.Ş Amasya, Çorum, Ordu, Samsun, Sinop 12,7 10,2 8,0 19,3 9,4 Please also find the map of Turkey which demonstrates the DisRes illustrated by the author. 23 4.2.2. DisRes of Turkey (Graphic V) Illustration made by the author in accordance with the above-presented table. 24 4.3. An Important Development Affecting DisRes On July 2005, Law 5398 which amended EML was enacted. By this amendment, a new concept which did not exist in EML prior to this amendment has been created. That is Organized Industrial Zones (OIZ) [Organize Sanayi Bölgeleri]. According to this; OIZ are entitled to conduct activities in generation, distribution within the approved borders in order to meet the demands of their participants upon receiving associated license. 91 In practice that means that the number of distribution companies may increase to over 100. It is not clear, for example, whether each zones will sign a vesting contract. Apparently the main purpose for this change is to ensure cheap electricity to industry. 92 4.4. Why Did the Distribution Take First Place in Privatization? The privatization in TEI will be commenced in distribution. The reason mentioned in SP is as follows; “Since the distribution companies, holding retail licenses and operating in liberal market, have to create confidence on investors engaged or to be engaged in generation activities, privatization will start in the distribution sub-sector.” 93 This policy may be justified by the assertion of proving comfort to new players in generation due to they will be in need of proving constant cash flow for loans required realizing the investments. While this process continues, the state-owned generators will be disaggregated by way of forming portfolio companies. Preventing the concentration among portfolio companies will also be aimed in this duration. 4.5. How Will the DisCos be Privatized? 4.5.1. Why Has TOR Been Chosen? Even the most preferred method for privatization, generally, is the transfer of ownership, TOR method was opted in Turkey in order to prevent possible supreme courts (Constitution Court of Turkey and Council of State) intervention in privatization. One of the main reasons of this consideration is that Constitution Court of Turkey, in 1994, 91 It has become the Article 2/g of EML Directly taken from: See, Supra n90 93 See, Supra n37 92 25 delivered the annulment decision with respect to privatization as per provisions of Law 3291 which envisaged privatization through transfer of ownership. The reasoning of the Court is as follows 94 ; 1. Transfer of ownership to foreigners; transferring the ownership of the public services having strategic importance without any restrictions conflicts with provisions of the constitution. 2. Monopoly and abuse of consumers; the measures that have to be taken in order to prevent monopoly and to protect consumers rights have not been implemented properly. Hence, it conflicts with the provisions of 167th and 172nd articles of the constitution. 3. Transfer of ownership of natural resources; the natural resources such as water or coal or etc. used in the generation can not be privatized within the assets of the generation facilities under the 168th article of the constitution due to they are subject to the ultimate ownership of the state. 4.5.2. The Steps To Be Taken During the Privatization Process Here is the simplified road map that is being used for the privatization process; 95 9 Defining Distribution Regions; as it has been mentioned above, Turkey has been divided into 21 DisRes in pursuant to HPC decision in SP. The number of DisRes is criticized by WB and other international Institutions in terms of exorbitance number of DisRes as the geographical attributes and technical data taken into consideration. In other words, Turkey may be said to have too small DisRes. 9 Corporatisation of DisCos; As of August 2006, Corporatisation of DisCos which is a mandatory conduct of unbundling and liberalization has been implemented properly. 94 Turkish Competition Authority (official web site), 1st Circuit Opinion with respect to Privatization of TEDAS (2005), at http://www.rekabet.gov.tr/word/gorus/tedasgorus.doc (last visited on 8 August 2006) in Turkish. 95 Taken from TCA’s Opinion and modified by the author. 26 9 Signing TOR Agreements; 96 TOR agreements were concluded between TEDAS and recently formed DisCos, in other words, between two state owned institutions. This is also important, because the company who wins the bid is to be undertaking all provisions of TOR agreement in which it can not change any provisions. Hence, this way of signing TOR agreements have been negatively commented by concerned investors. There are a lot of controversial provisions in TOR agreements that can deteriorate willingness of the investors such as the provision stipulating any investment to be realized within this contract term by DisCos will belong to state. 97 Also, in the event of abstention of required investments supposed to be done by DisCos, EMRA are authorized revoke the given licenses under EML. 9 Obtaining Distribution License for DisCos; Any legal entity that is conducting business or intends to do so has to obtain Distribution License from EMRA under EML. 9 Signing Electricity Energy Sales Agreements; these are the agreements that are named as “transition contracts”. Such as; • Transition Contracts between the DisCos and the GenCos (portfolio companies and Private GenCos) 98 ; These contracts should be put in place before distribution companies are privatized to give the generation companies/ groups a track record prior to their privatization. The contracts should continue after the privatization to assure a predictable stream of revenues in the early years. 99 • Transition contracts between the DisCos and TETAS; The energy purchased by TETAS through “existing contracts” and EUAS Generation, will be allocated among the DisCos through purchase agreements to be signed between TETAS and DisCos. In case TETAS is unable to recover adequate 96 EML Article 14; “An agreement for transfer of operational rights may be signed among TEDAŞ and the electricity distribution companies established to operate within the determined distribution regions save for the ownership of TEDAŞ on the facilities and assets required for the distribution activity and are within TEDAŞ’s field of operation.” 97 This condition is stipulated by the 21st Article of Law 5398. Also, written in TOR agreements. 98 See, Supra n37. See also, Provisional Article 10 of EML 99 See, Supra n37 27 revenues to cover its liabilities arising from long term contracts, these excess liabilities will be recovered through a surcharge to be added on the transmission use of system charges. 100 • Transition contracts between the EUAS hydro generation and TETAS 101 The generation of the hydro power plants that are not included within disaggregation process and will be under the possession of EUAS shall continue to selling to TETAS as long as it is deemed necessary to achieve an average TETAS sales price in order to mitigate high prices of electricity of PPMs. 9 Finally, the shares of the companies will be sold; at the end of the privatization term, the shares of the DisCos who signed the transition contracts will be sold to the investors. Since this conduct is regarded as a change in share holder scheme, it will be subject to approval of TCA, and any required amendments will be made in the associated licenses. [Please See the Annex – 1 which demonstrates the schedule of TENDER PROCESS in detail, attached to this paper.] 4.6. Technical Loss & Theft Problems One of the most important problems in privatization of distribution is the high level of differences among DisRes in terms of technical lose and theft. (See the table in section 4.2.1.) The ratio is highest in the east and southeast part of Turkey where annual income per head is said to be less than 3,000 USD and these regions have a chronic terror problem since mid 1980s. Another indicator is that the level of technical lose and theft is very high in Istanbul because of outstanding and increasing suburban habitants which are consequent of domestic migration. 102 It seems that distribution is going to be privatized before conducting any effort to reduce loses. In regions where loss ratios are very high, it is doubtful that passing the task of reducing losses over to the private sector is a wise policy. 103 Atiyas also suggests that reducing losses before privatization by public authorities would be a better policy. 100 Id. Id. 102 Job opportunities and new investments are the main reasons for domestic immigration to Istanbul. 103 See, Supra n90 101 28 The cost of technical lose and theft is currently financed through a national retail tariff, which entails cross subsidies from regions with low ratios to those where the ratios are high. Such a system of cross subsidies will not voluntarily survive once distribution is privatized. 104 Also any other system which does not provide any subsidies will be both unfair and politically unacceptable due to that will surely lead to large inter-regional differences in retail prices for non-eligible consumers. 105 There is no doubt that Turkey will face vital social problems in those regions such as increasing terror in those regions.106 Further information with respect to tariffs is provided below. 4.7. Tariff Regulations Tariff regulations are important in market. The main purposes of regulations are to prevent monopoly and to secure the consumers welfare. The basic regulations regarding tariffs of TEI are EML and Electricity Market Tariff Regulation. Also, SP envisages a tariff regulation which conflicts with the provisions of associated legislation. 107 As it is mentioned above, there are high level differences between DisRes in terms of technical lose and theft in Turkey. Since the technical lose and theft levels of DisRes are inextricable components of the price of electricity and the price of electricity has a social dimension, it is vitally important to Turkish State to prevent any price fluctuations which can cause social reactions. Even EML does not envisage any subsidies and just states direct cash payments to consumers in these regions in order to prevent those kinds of undesired situations, SP takes another approach and stipulates the establishment of a “Price Equalization Mechanism” (PEM) [Fiyat Eşitleme Mekanizması]. PEM is also called as National Tariff that will be in force for five years after the privatization. In order to prevent price differentiation among DisRes which may arise as a result of liberalization of the industry, subsidization will be performed, under SP, within this “transition period” by way of conducting cross–subsidies from regions with low ratios to those where the ratios are high. In other words, this 104 105 106 107 Id. Id. Contrary to general belief of foreigners, the most important reason behind Terror in southeast part Turkey is certainly an economic problem (low annual income rate per person, and low education ratio, etc.) rather than a political or identity conflicts. (the author’s opinion). See, Supra n37 29 “transition period” which expires by the end of December 2010, has been defined for the purpose of balancing the tariffs between the DisRes. 108 This equalization mechanism will be implemented to align the principle of achieving cost reflective regional tariffs for the DisRes, with the objective of ensuring uniform national tariffs for non-eligible consumers. At the end of this period, the tariffs are to be defined by the market itself by taking cost and other imbursements into consideration (cost based tariff calculation). TCA approves PEM and finds this mechanism useful, however it also stresses the importance of achieving a competitive market by the end of transition period. 109 5. COMPETITION Even competition issues of TEI arising from privatization are deserved to be addressed in a separate research paper due to they are very controversial, they are addressed here from general perspective. 5.1. Which Will Prevail, EML or SP? Even SP which outlines the major steps to be taken as privatizing the industry, is not legally binding due to it is not a Code, it is easy to state that it is as powerful as applicable legislation due to any required amendments to applicable legislation is made in pursuant to SP. One of the examples to this power is the amendment made in EML by Law 5398 in 2006. (See section 5.2.) We are telling about this power because SP has conflicting provisions with EML. The conflicting provisions between EML and SP are mostly related to competition issues. EML envisages privatization of distribution activities separately from retail activities whereas SP envisages privatization of these two activities together. Hence, while EML entitles non-eligible consumers to acquire their electricity from either DisCos or RetCos in their region, SP mandates non-eligible consumers to acquire their electricity solely from 108 109 Id. See, Supra n94 30 DisCos that will also engage in retail activities under SP. 110 As of today, even TCA delivered its opinion in favor of the prediction set out in EML, it seems that the privatization will be realized in accordance with SP. Many commentators criticize the privatization of distribution activities together with retail activities due to its position to slowing down of introduction of competition in retail markets. It is also possible to say that this means vesting monopoly rents to tender winner. It is generally believed by public that these steps have been undertaken to increase privatization revenues or to make these assets more attractive for tender participants. The notion “making assets more attractive” not only conflicts with the statement made in SP 111 but it also conflicts with the Opinion delivered by the TCA. Privatizations should be conducted for the purpose of introducing competition into the electricity industry. 5.2. Law 5893 and Vertical Integration On July 2005, Law 5398, which amended some provisions of EML, was enacted. 112 This is one of the most controversial issues in recent times due to this Law stipulates some important modifications in EML such as; Law 5398 allows DisCos to build their own GenCos by fulfilling two requirements. The First one is “accounting separation” between companies and the second one is “sale price of electricity” between DisCos and GenCos which DisCos own or affiliated to, can be no higher than the average sale price of wholesale market. 113 Before the enactment of this Law, engaging in generation activities of DisCos had been restricted to 20% of the total electricity supplied in that region in preceding year under EML. 114 There is no restriction exists on DisCos in terms of their engagement in electricity generation as per Law 5398. This explicitly means that Law 5398 provides integration opportunity to DisCos and GenCos. This is a vitally important issue in terms of vertical unbundling which means separation of activities of transmission and distribution from the activities of generation and retail. This conduct is one of the most important “sine qua non” activities for any 110 111 112 113 114 See, Supra n37 Id. “the privatization approach will not be solely aimed at the maximization of privatization income.” See, Supra n5 Article 22 of Law 5398 It was article 3/c-3 of EML before it was revoked. 31 country decided to liberalize its electricity industry and introduce it into competition. This notion is based on the fact that transmission and distribution are natural monopolies. Hence, without assuring third party access, the competition will not be introduced into industry. By doing so means the natural monopoly is just transferred from public to private. The private actors will surely try to increase their rent by way of restricting other participants. Therefore, assuring the competition in TEI will not be easy. Atiyas mentions that, change was introduced during discussions at the parliamentary committee and was not applied to EMRA for its opinion. No reason for this important change was released to the public. It was widely interpreted as a move to increase the privatization revenue of distribution companies and an incitement given to potential buyers of those assets. Besides this amendment, EU directives require distribution to be at least legally separated from retail supply and generation in member countries until 2007. The directives stipulate additional measures to ensure independent decision making, in case distribution is legally separated but is controlled by groups that also control generation or retail supply activities. 115 In a recent sector inquiry carried out by the European Commission, vertical integration and foreclosure is identified as a major impediment to competition. 116 TCA also stated that distribution should be at least legally unbundled, if the separation of ownership might not be conducted. 117 This separation will be the ultimate condition for the approval of privatization.118 Under Turkish Law, privatization transactions are treated no different than a normal acquisition or merger. As a result, these privatizations are also subject to ultimate approval authority of TCA. This is very important because if the bids are conducted without making required modifications stipulated by TCA would, most probably, be terminated by TCA. TCA also asserted that the provisions under SP had been set forth in favor of supply security and foreign investment; however the consumer rights and competition issues not addressed properly. 115 See, Supra n90 Id. 117 See, Supra n94 118 Id. 116 32 6. CONCLUSION Restructuring or Reform Period of TEI was commenced as a result of insufficient public funds and poor performance of public electricity monopoly as well as the advices given by the international institutions such as WB and IMF. After the codification of EML, stateowned monopoly was unbundled into generation, wholesale, transmission, distribution and retail sale segments in parallel to the provisions of EML by the Decree of CoM in 2001. However, SP which envisages the major steps to be taken in order to realize the privatization was issued by HPC in 2004 and it has conflicting provisions with EML. Even we mentioned above and do not intention to repeat the competition issues here again, we also want to stress the importance of the amendment made in EML by Law 5398 because if the coming bids are realized as per Law 5398 they would, most probably, be terminated by either Constitution Court or by CoS if not terminated by TCA based on the maxims exist in associated legislations. Besides these developments which are carried out by the government in order to increase the privatization revenue of distribution companies, there are some other developments which are also carried by the same government in order to demonstrate to public or to the newspapers that the state control over the assets having “strategic importance” will not be lost. As parallel to this notion TOR agreements in which indigestible provisions such as termination of the contract by TEDAS without paying any imbursement or responsibility disclaimer of TEDAS exist, concluded between two state-owned institutions (TEDAS and newly formed DisCos) prior to conducting privatization. Hence, the bid winner will have to bear TOR’s conditions that he has no authority to change. In short, the government desires not to lose control over DisCos whilst it still wants to increase privatization revenue. This confusion in government’s notion also reflects in the applicable legislation which gives rise to regulatory uncertainty. We believe that Government should opt to publish a policy text (may be a “white paper” first) in order to reduce this kind of regulatory uncertainty in industry. This text would not only refresh academic works also would help government to gain public support which is an important component of privatization.119 This can be fallowed by a “green paper” 119 See, Supra n3 33 which would provide information about recent developments in the reform process and the problems faced. 120 Such an approach would also help generate a meeting of minds among different agencies responsible for energy policy. In addition, publications of regulatory decisions with their reasoning would contribute significantly to transparency. 121 From the above, it is easy to conclude that even Turkey has moved forward a lot since the codification of EML in terms of restructuring the industry, there are still important issues waiting to be addressed or to be settled between concerned state and private parties of the process. Consequently, Turkey has got on electricity privatization boat which has a long journey. Hence, Turkey has a long way to take and lots to learn by this full of experience journey. 120 121 See, Supra n90 Id. 34 7. ANNEX – 1 The below given diagram is directly taken from Osman Demirci’s work. 122 122 Ph.D. Demirci, O., TEDAS Privatization (March 2006), at www.turkey-now.com/db/docs/osman_demir ci.pdf (last visited on 29 August 2006). 35 8. BIBLIOGRAPHY 8.1. PRIMARY SOURCES 8.1.1. National Legislation (Selected Laws and Regulation) Law 4628 (entered into force March 2001) Law 4046 (entered into force November 1994) Law 3996 (entered into force June 1994) Law 3096 (entered into force December 1984) Electricity Market Balancing and Settlement Regulation (entered into force November 2004) 8.2. SECONDARY SOURCES 8.2.1. Books Atiyas, I., Liberalization and Regulatory Reform in Electricity Sector, (Istanbul: Turkey, TESEV Publications, 2006) in Turkish. Serhat Guney, E., Restructuring, Competition, and Regulation in the Turkish Electricity Industry (Istanbul: Turkey, TEPAV Publication, 2005). 8.2.2. Articles Cetin, T., Oguz, F., The Politics of Regulation in the Turkish Electricity Market, Energy Policy Journal, article in press, at doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2006.05.014 (last visited on 07 August 2006). Erdogdu, E., Regulatory Reform in Turkish Energy Industry: An analysis, Energy Policy Journal, article in press, at doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2006.02.011 (last visited on 07 August 2006). Hepbasli, A., Development and Restructuring of Turkey’s Electricity Sector: a Review, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 9 (2005), at 311-343. 36 Ozkıvrak, O., Electricity Restructuring in Turkey, Energy Policy Journal 33 (2005), at 1339-1350. 8.2.3. Research Paper Bodur, C., Regulatory Framework of Build-Operate-Transfer Model in Turkey, (submitted Research Paper for International Project Finance course at CEPMLP, April 2006). 8.2.4. Internet Sources BEDAS, History of Electricity in Istanbul, at http://www.bedas.gov.tr/bedas/tarihce.php (last visited on 07 August 2006) in Turkish. Energy Market Regulatory Authority (official web site), Annual Report (2005), at www.epdk.gov.tr/yayin_ rapor/yillik/yillik.htm (last visited on 7 August 2006). High Planning Council, Electricity Sector Reform and Privatization Strategy, at www.oib.gov.tr/program/2004_program/2004_electricity_strategy_paper.htm (last visited on 7 August 2006). International Energy Agency, Turkey Country Analysis Brief (June 2005), at www.eia.doe. gov/emeu/cabs/turkey.html (last visited on 7 August 2006). Kulali, I., Electricity Sector and Privatization studies in Turkey, at http://ekutup.dpt.gov.tr/ kit/kulalii/elektrik.html (last visited on 7 August 2006) in Turkish. Ph.D. Demirci, O., TEDAS Privatization (March 2006), at www.turkey-now.com/db/docs/ osman_demir ci.pdf (last visited on 29 August 2006). Pritchard, R., Eight Guidelines of Electricity Industry Reform, Vol. 12-7 Article. Online Journal CEPMLP (August 2002) at www.dundee.ac.uk/cepmlp/journal/html/volume12.php (last visited on 10 August 2006). 37 Pritchard, R., Andrews-Speed, P., Eight Principles of Electricity Industry Reform, Vol. 7-2 Article. Online Journal CEPMLP (July 2000) at www.dundee.ac.uk/cepmlp/journal/html/ volume 7. php (last visited on 10 August 2006). State Auditing Agency, Research Report With Respect to applications of BOT and TOR, at www.tccb.gov. tr/tr_html/DDK/enerji.htm (last visited on 07 August 2006) in Turkish. Turkish Competition Authority (official web site), 1st Circuit Opinion with respect to Privatization of TEDAS (2005), at http://www.rekabet.gov.tr/word/gorus/tedasgorus.doc (last visited on 8 August 2006) in Turkish. Turkish Electricity Distribution Co. (official web site), History of the Institution, at http://www.tedas.gov.tr/1,Hakkimizda.html (last visited on 07 August 2006) in Turkish. Turkish Electricity Trading and Contracting Co. (official web site), at www.tetas.gov.tr/ tanitimson.htm (last visited on 7 August 2006) in Turkish. 38