Measuring Revenue Performance
Transcription
Measuring Revenue Performance
Final Report Mobilizing Resources through Reform of State Non-tax Sources for Plan Development Mahesh C Purohit Vishnu Kanta Purohit Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research New Delhi-110052 Final Report Mobilizing Resources through Reform of State Non-tax Sources for Plan Development (Study Sponsored by the Planning Commission, Government of India) Mahesh C Purohit Vishnu Kanta Purohit Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research 133, SFS, Ashok Vihar-IV New Delhi-110052 Phone: 27305008; 27301758 Fax: 27302802 e-mail: [email protected] website : www.fpepr.org Research Team Dr. Mahesh C Purohit Project Leader Dr (Mrs) Vishnu Kanta Purohit Hon. Consultant Dr. Amrat L Meena Research Associate Ms Madhulika Research Associate Soumya Ranjan Biswal Research Associate CONTENTS Sl. No. List of Tables List of Exhibits Preface 1 Introduction Page iv v vi 1 Objectives of the Study Taxonomy of Non-tax Resources Scope of the Study User Charges Optimal Recoveries on Public Services: A Theoretical Perspective Methodology of the Study Sources of Data Scheme of Presentation 2 Annexure A.1.1 Classification of Non-tax Revenue in State Budgets 12 Fiscal Significance of States’ Own Non-tax Sources 14 Composition and Trends in States’ Own Non-tax Revenues Components of States’ Own Non-tax Revenues Receipts from General Services Receipts from Social Services Receipts from Economic Services Components of Social Services Components of Economic Services Summing-up i 3 Pricing Strategy for Non-tax Sources 46 Introduction Issues in Utility Pricing Theories of Utility Pricing Concept of Costs Problems of Measurability Designing User Charges Conclusion 4 Revenue Realization from Non-tax Sources 67 Issues in Determination of User Charges Actual Cost Recovery Desired Percentage of RR/RE Conclusions 5 Annexure A.4.1 (a) RR/RE of Different Components of Social Services Annexure A.4.1 (b) RR/RE of Different Components of Economic Services Annexure A.4.2 (a) Regression Results for Phase I Annexure A.4.2 (b) Regression Results for Phase II Annexure A.4.3 (a) Regression Results with Dummy Variables for Phase I Annexure A.4.3 (b) Regression Results with Dummy Variables for Phase II 91 Rationalising Structure of Non-tax Sources 96 92 94 94 95 95 Education Medical and Public Health Water Supply and Sanitation Forest and Wild life Irrigation Royalty on Mines and Minerals Roads and Bridges 6 Procedural Reforms for Non-tax Revenue and Issues in Delivery of Services 123 Complexities in Procedures in Delivery of Services ii Education Medical and Public Health Water Supply and Sanitation Rationalisation of Procedures in Delivery of Services as Fiscal Measure Conclusion 7 Summary of Conclusions and Policy Imperatives 134 Annexures 141 Annexure A.1: Questionnaire for Collecting Data for a Study on Non-tax Sources For Planned Development Annexure A.2: Rates of User Charges for Different Services for Select States Annexure A.3: Constitutional Provision Related to Regulation and Development of Mines and Mineral Sector Annexure A.4: Rates of Royalty and Dead Rent for Minerals (2000-01) 142 Appendixes 194 Appendix A: Revenue Receipts Tables for 15 Major States Budget Data (1993-96 and 2001-04) Appendix B: Revenue Expenditure Tables for 15 Major States Budget Data (1993-96 and 2001-04) Appendix C: Tables from RBI Revenue Receipts from 1993-94 to 2003-04 Appendix D: Tables from RBI Revenue Expenditure from 1993-94 to 2003-04 200 References 283 163 189 190 219 253 273 iii Table No. 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 2.8 2.9 2.10 2.11 2.12 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.6 4.7 4.8 4.9 4.10 4.11 4.12 5.1 5.2 5.3 5.4 5.5 List of Tables Title Non-tax Revenue in Different Countries All-States Own Non-tax Revenue and its Composition State-wise Own Non-tax Revenue and its Composition The Role of Education etc. in Social Services, SONTR and GSDP The Role of Medical and Public Health in Social Services, SONTR and GSDP The Role of Urban Development in Social Services and SONTR The Role of Water Supply and Sanitation in Social Services and SONTR The Role of Forestry and Wildlife in Economic Services, SONTR and GSDP The Role of Irrigation Projects in Economic Services and SONTR The Role of Major and Medium Irrigation in Economic Services and SONTR The Role of Minor Irrigation in Economic Services and SONTR The Role of Industries in Economic Services and SONTR RR/RE for Social and Economic Services Average RR/RE of Select Services Deviation from Norms for Public Works Deviation from Norms for Education, Sports, Arts and Culture Deviation from Norms for Medical and Public Health Deviation from Norms for Water Supply and Sanitation Deviation from Norms for Forestry and Wildlife Deviation from Norms for Major and Medium Irrigation Deviation from Norms for Minor Irrigation Deviation from Norms for Industries Deviation from Norms for Royalties on Mines and Minerals Deviation from Norms for Roads and Bridges RR/RE from Elementary, Secondary and Higher Education in Major States Household, Public and Total Health Expenditure in India (2004-05) Forest Cover in Different States in India Methods for Valuing Forest Benefits Toll Collection of Major States Page 32 35 36 38 38 39 39 40 40 41 41 42 78 79 81 81 82 82 83 83 84 84 85 85 118 119 120 121 122 iv List of Exhibits S. No. Title Page 2.1 Components of All-States Own Non-tax Revenue 43 2.2 (a) Share of Components of Social Services (1993-94) 44 (b) Share of Components of Social Services (2003-04) 44 (a) Share of Components of Economic Services (1993-94) 45 (b) Share of Components of Economic Services (2003-04) 45 4.1 Deviation from Norms for Public Works 86 4.2 Deviation from Norms for Education etc. 86 4.3 Deviation from Norms for Medical and Public Health 87 4.4 Deviation from Norms for Water Supply and Sanitation 87 4.5 Deviation from Norms for Forestry and Wildlife 88 4.6 Deviation from Norms for Major and Medium Irrigation 88 4.7 Deviation from Norms for Minor Irrigation 89 4.8 Deviation from Norms for Industries 89 4.9 Deviation from Norms for Royalties on Mines and Minerals 90 4.10 Deviation from Norms for Roads and Bridges 90 2.3 v Preface The Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research is an autonomous, non-profit organization whose major functions are to carry out research, undertake consultancy work, and conduct training in the area of public economics and policy. The Foundation undertook this study at the instance of the Socio Economic Research Division of the Planning Commission, Government of India. The main objectives of this study are to analyze the existing structure of non-tax sources in the Indian States and to recommend requisite changes in its structure, so as to enable the States to mobilize resources for development. This study is the result of the collective effort of the project team of the Institute under the guidance of Mahesh C. Purohit, who prepared the final draft of the study. We acknowledge the valuable contributions made by the other members of the team, especially Dr. (Mrs) Vishnu Kanta Purohit who contributed to the study tremendously and provided unstinting support, including the preparation of the draft of some of the chapters. The authors are grateful to the Socio Economic Research Division of the Planning Commission for sanctioning this study and providing them with an opportunity to give a mid-term presentation of the study. Thanks are due to Dr. Amrat Lal Meena and Ms Madhulika who provided excellent research assistance through out the tenure of this study and helped in the analysis of relevant data and issues. Dr. Amrat Lal Meena, along with. Mr Varun Aggarwal and Ms Shikha Goel, specially contributed in collection, collation and analysis of relevant data from the Reserve Bank of India Bulletins and the State Budget Documents. Ms Madhulika, in addition to analysis of data, contributed to preparing the base material for the report and also prepared preliminary draft of a few chapters. Competent research assistance provided by Mr Soumya Ranjan Biswal, at the later stage of this study, is also gratefully acknowledged. Collection of data on user charges and an in-depth understanding of the procedural aspects required visiting the State capitals of Rajasthan, Maharashtra, Karnataka and West Bengal. The authors want to express their gratitude to the Secretaries of the select services of the respective State Governments, who spared time in discussing the issues related to revenue receipts from these services. The authors want to express their gratitude to Drs. D N Rao, Gautam Naresh and G. L. Aggarwal for their valuable insights during the course of work on the project. They are also thankful to Shri R. Sridharan, K M Alimalmigothi, A K Panda, O P Shemar (Planning Commission) and to Shri V S Senthil (Ministry of Finance) for their suggestions made during the course of the mid-term presentation at the Planning Commission. Special thanks are due to Drs. Anwar Shah, Arindam Das Gupta, and Brijesh C Purohit for their comments on the methodology and the results of the study. The Governing Body of the Foundation does not bear any responsibility for the contents or views expressed in the report. The responsibility rests with the authors, in particular, the leader of the team. New Delhi December 22, 2006 Mahesh C Purohit Director 1 Introduction Augmenting resources for the States is an intricate exercise involving balancing current revenues, economic growth and the political economy of the system. Mobilising resources is not a pure economic exercise; it has political dimensions as well. The political economy of mobilising resources, therefore, has to consider issues related to both - the economic effects and the fall out in terms of politics. Mobilising resources through reforms in non-tax sources serves the twin purpose of having a rational non-tax structure and generating greater means to achieve economic growth. Irrational structure of non-tax sources has adverse economic effects that invalidate growth objectives. From the economic point of view, therefore, one has to keep in mind the objectives of equity, efficiency and neutrality; especially the impact of these on the economic growth of the economy. To fulfil these objectives, one often tends to adopt an economically rational structure of non-tax sources that may not be palatable politically. A popularly elected Government, therefore, has to adopt a balance between the two. Objectives of the Study Given the political economy of mobilising resources, this study aims at presenting measures for mobilising resources via reforms in non-tax sources. In doing so, it adheres to the objectives of: a. analyzing the structure of States’ non-tax sources, b. examining the structural reforms and suggesting a rational non-tax structure; which should be economically viable and should yield larger resources; c. suggesting fiscal measures in terms of procedural reforms for removing harassment to consumers of utilities, making structural reforms politically palatable; and d. recommending reforms related to institutional preparedness - a pre-requisite for mobilising additional resources. Thus, this study hypothesizes that the non-tax revenues should form a sizable portion of the States’ own revenues in India. The current contribution of States own non-tax revenues is about 19 percent of the States own revenue receipts. It is, therefore, appropriate that attention is gradually turned to measures to increase non-tax revenues. This is imperative given the widening revenue expenditure gaps in the States’ budgeting and the growing public resentment against attempts to raise more revenue through taxation. The structural reforms in tax administration in the country has led to a wide-spread demand to reduce the quantum of subsidy and to meet the cost of public services through proper pricing, wherever this is feasible. The general perception is that ‘free of user charges’ public services should not exist. The user charges should be fixed according to the economic status of the user and the nature or type of the commodity. This should be such that the cost is met and the market price of the commodity does not lead to over-consumption of such services and wasteful use of scarce resources. Taxonomy of Non-Tax Resources Non-tax sources are defined, as payment made to the Government for which there is a quid pro quo 1 . However, these non-tax sources do not have similar features and are classified into three categories: First, there are some sources that are compulsory and requited payments. These sources include penalties (other than penalties on non-compliance of taxes)2 and fines. The second category consists of voluntary and unrequited receipts. These payments include donations and contributions made to the Government or any unclaimed funds lying with the Government. The third category comprises voluntary and requited payments, including revenue earned from the resources owned by the Government such as forest, marine, riparian habitats and wildlife. This category also has revenue earned by sale of usage rights, admission fee, as well as the royalties and rental payments received by the Government. Income earned in the form of dividends and the interest receipts from investments made by the Government also fall into this category. 1 This is in contrast with the definition of tax as a compulsory payment made to the Government for which there is no quid pro quo. See Dalton, Huge. 1949. Principles of Public Finance. Routledge and Kegan Paul Ltd., p.32. London. 2 Musgrave, Richard A. and Peggy B Musgrave. 1989. Public Finance in Theory and Practice, 5th edition, McGraw Hill Book Company, Boston. 2 Scope of the Study Though the term ‘non-tax revenue’ encompasses all the above components, some of the non-tax sources (payments made to the Government for which there is a quid pro quo) are not included in this study. This has been done to delimit the scope of this study and to have a thorough analysis of some of the services. First, payments made to the Government in the form of subscription to a loan or to a long-term saving scheme, which is repayable by the Government in the future (that is, the payment made to the Government is requited by future payments or by transfer of other assets) is considered as ‘capital receipts’ and is not included in the scope of non-tax revenue. The other similar receipts excluded from the purview of this study are Government borrowings, money creation or proceeds of disinvestments. Second, revenue receipts of the Government through the sale of goods and services (that are commercial in nature) are also not included in the scope of this study. In this context, it is important to point out that it is possible to alter the legal scope of Governmental activities and thereby, the scope of non-tax revenue, without in anyway modifying the underlying economic reality. For example, it is possible to transfer a departmental undertaking (e.g. Milk Scheme run by the Government) as a public sector organisation, which subsequently affects the flow of non-tax revenue of the Government without in anyway altering the economic scope of the governmental activities. The problem arises when one State Government includes such an organisation as part of the budget while another State does not. For example, the Punjab Roadways run by the department is a part of the governmental non-tax sources while the PEPSU Road Transport Corporation (a non-departmental organization) is not a part of the nontax sources. Differences in the scope of Government across the States, therefore, limit the comparability of data from all States. Hence, this study excludes such services. Thirdly, in some non-tax receipts it is observed that not all receipts by the Government are accounted for in its consolidated fund, e.g. in education, although the students pay a variety of fees, only the tuition fees are credited to the treasury 3 . Similarly, in medical and public health, it is observed that in some States the user charges paid by out-door patients are not put into the consolidated fund. In Rajasthan this is credited to the welfare of the hospital staff and in Tamil Nadu it is considered to be a part of the maintenance expenditure of the hospital. Such variations inhibit a comparative analysis of recovery rate of different services. It is, therefore, desirable to include all non-tax receipts in the consolidated fund. Fourthly, the revenue from lotteries is netted out because the purpose of this activity is not to provide any public service but to generate revenue. In many States, a major chunk of the revenue from lotteries is used to make payment for lottery prizes. Only a very small proportion of this revenue remains with the State Government. The same holds true for other commercial 3 Tilak, J B G. 1993. “Financing Higher Education in India: Principles, Practice and Policy Issues”. Higher Education. Netherlands. 26(1), July: 43-67. 3 activities. Therefore, this study uses the concept of net non-tax revenue i.e. gross non-tax revenue minus expenditure for these commercial activities. Finally, notional receipts are excluded from the purview of this study, e.g. interest on capital works in irrigation, which is matched by contra-entry in many States (signifying notional expenditure). Thus, the term non-tax revenue in this study comprises revenue receipts (i.e. noncapital receipts) excluding accruals and taxes of all the tiers of Government, as well as notional receipts matched by contra-expenditure. The study, however, confines its scope to only those non-tax sources, which originate from the administrative departments and departmental undertakings. These are of a noncommercial nature. Therefore, sources such as interest, profits and dividends arising from the States’ commercial undertakings are beyond its scope. The non-tax sources covered in the study include the following: Administrative Non-tax Receipts This source accounts for about three-fourths of the States’ own non-tax revenue. In the future, this is likely to be the most productive and reliable source of non-tax revenues for the States. There are over 100 departmental sources of non-tax revenues in different States which are classified under three dozen heads. Thus, in attempting a broad study of all the items under non-tax sources, the effort is to cover some aspects from each of the three broad components of administrative receipts, viz. general services, social services, and economic services. A. Receipts from General Services These comprise receipts from Public Service Commission, Police, Jails, Supplies and disposals, Stationery and printing, Public works, Other administrative services, Contribution and recoveries towards pension and other retirement benefits, and Other miscellaneous general services. Details regarding revenue from General Services are listed below: (a) Revenue accrues from fees charged from candidates appearing for various competitive examinations and interviews conducted by the Public Service Commission (PSC). The volume of the receipts under this head directly depends upon the nature and the number of examinations held by the Commission during a year and the number of candidates appearing for the examination. (b) Police comprises reimbursement receipts from the Government of India and other States towards the cost of police supplied (forming the bulk of the revenue under the major 4 head), cost of police supplied to autonomous bodies, private companies and persons, receipts under the Arms Act, as well as sale proceeds of unserviceable articles, collection of payments for services rendered, recovery of overpayments and miscellaneous receipts and so on. (c) Jails comprise receipts from sale of articles manufactured in jail factories and farm produce of the jails. (d) Stationery and Printing department comprise sale proceeds of stationery supply to Government departments run on commercial lines, sale proceeds of State Gazette, printing charges for Government departments and other miscellaneous receipts. (e) The Public Works Department (PWD) has rental income from Government buildings, hire charges of machinery supplied to the contractors as well as the percentage charges. (f) Revenue from other administrative sources consists of receipts pertaining to administration of justice, elections, civil defence, fire protection etc. (g) Pension contributions from other Governments, autonomous bodies, local bodies etc. in respect of Government servants placed on deputation fall in this category. It also includes Government share in Contributory Provident Fund (CPF) and interest thereon. (h) Other miscellaneous general services include numerous small receipts from sources such as unclaimed deposits, allotment and sale of land, receipts relating to guarantees given by Government, sale of old stores, shares and materials, urban assessments etc. A substantial portion of the general services revenue comes from numerous other administrative services and other miscellaneous receipts including written off loans. However, if these are excluded, the major receipts are from police, public works, and pension funds. B. Receipts from Social Services The major items that come under this class are (a) Education, sports, arts and culture, (b) Medical and public health, (c) Family welfare, (d) Water supply and sanitation, (e) Housing, (f) Urban development (g) Information and publicity, (h) Labour and employment, (i) Social security and welfare, and (j) Other social services. The main receipts from these social services are given below: (a) Receipts from tuition and other fees realized from students in Government educational institutions, public contributions to the educational institutions, receipts of museums and archaeological monuments. 5 (b) Receipts from Employees State Insurance Corporation (ESIC), medical receipts including contributions from patients, and tuition fees from the medical colleges, wherever located. (c) Family welfare receipts are contribution of the users, and receipts on account of strengthening of family welfare. (d) The water supply and sanitation receipts comprise service fees, percentage charges from other Government departments, and receipts from water schemes. (e) Housing receipts are the rental receipts for the quarters constructed under the industrial housing scheme under the charge of PWD. Other items are receipts accruing from the sale of master plans, license fees from cinema halls, rental incomes of Devasthans as also various fees under the labour and trade laws. A major portion of the receipts from social services is due to water supply and sanitation charges. Another substantial part is derived from education, sports, art and culture (ESAC) services (this share has fallen over time), and medical and public health services. There has been rapid growth in the receipts from water supply and sanitation, medical and public health, urban development and family welfare services. C. Receipts from Economic Services Major items under this class are (a) Crop husbandry, (b) Animal husbandry, (c) Dairy development, (d) Fisheries, (e) Forestry and wild life, (f) Co-operation, (g) Other agricultural and rural programmes, (h) Special area programmes, (i) Major and medium irrigation, (j) Minor irrigation, (k) Village and small scale industries, (l) Industries, (m) Non-ferrous mining and metallurgical industries, (n) Roads and bridges, (o) Tourism, and (p) Others. In many of the States, the largest contributor under the category of economic services is receipt from the mines and mineral department, which accounts for over a half of the total receipts from this category. Other major contributors are receipts from irrigation, industries, forestry and wild life, and agricultural services. However, there has been a phenomenal increase in receipts accruing from roads and bridges, area development services, irrigation, cooperation and agriculture. Excluding the other administrative and miscellaneous sources from the general services category, there appears to be just ten major individual contributors to the States’ non-tax revenue. In view of the strategic importance of some of the services in the overall non-tax sources, the study has taken the following ten services for an in-depth analysis: (1) Public works, (2) Education, sports, art & culture, 6 (3) Medical, public health and family welfare, (4) Water supply and sanitation, (5) Forestry and wild life, (6) Major and medium irrigation, (7) Minor irrigation, (8) Industries, (9) Mines and minerals, and (10) Roads and Bridges. These accounts for about 2/3rd to 3/4th of the administrative component of the non-tax revenue in different States. This study makes a detailed analysis of the structure of revenue realized (RR) from these services in each State. It has also collected information on the user charges of these services for a few select States. The selected States are Rajasthan (Northern Zone), Karnataka (Southern Zone), Maharashtra (Western Zone) and West Bengal (Eastern Zone). User Charges The non-tax revenue in lieu of the provision of goods and services by the Government is derived through ‘user charges’. These charges indicate payments that are administratively determined for the goods and services provided by the Government 4 . As stated by the OECD, these are requited payments. However, the link between payments and services provided may vary considerably in terms of degree of cost recovery. These include payments in exchange for non-capital goods and services—e.g. charges for education and health; entry charge for museum, parks, etc.; and rent for housing. However, the OECD definition is subject to some ambiguities as it distinguishes between capital, and non-capital goods and services. The Government is providing capital goods in the form of urban infrastructure. These are used for domestic as well as for industrial purposes and accordingly, the user charges should also vary. More specifically, use of ‘user charges’ recognizes the necessity to include internal recharges between Government departments in order to avoid multiple counting 5 . Optimal Recoveries on Public Services: A Theoretical Perspective Government intervention in providing goods and services for public welfare can be justified on the grounds of market imperfection in provisions of these goods. The magnitude 4 Price is determined by market forces whereas user charges are fixed administratively; generally on principles different than those applied to price determination. 5 Stephen, Bailey J. 1994. “User charges for urban services”. Urban Studies, Vol. 31(4/5): 745-765. 7 and the mix of these goods provided by the Government will depend on the level of economic development and market imperfection. ‘Pure’ public goods are the ones having features of: (a) non-excludability i.e. where A’s consumption is made contingent on A’s paying the price, while B cannot be excluded for not paying the price, and (b) non-rival consumption / joint consumption i.e. A’s partaking of the consumption benefits do not reduce the benefits derived by all others. The same benefits are available to all, without mutual interference. In fact very few public goods are pure public goods. Firstly, the joint consumption property might be partly violated. Although all individuals may consume the services in the same quantity, the benefit obtained may be reduced as more persons have a share in its consumption. This phenomenon is known as congestion or partial rivalness. A number of authors 6 have distinguished between this type of public good on the basis of variability in the use or no variability in the use of public services. The variability in the use occurs due to some amount of opportunity cost involved in the use of these public services. Secondly, goods provided by the Government may have joint consumption features but these may be excludable. Such goods and services may be termed as ‘price-excludable public goods’7 . These are television and radio transmission and services provided by the transportation facilities, entertainment facilities (theatres, museum), recreational facilities (national parks, stadium) and information services. Theoretical foundations seem to have little impact on the charging practices for the goods and services provided by the Government in the developed/developing countries. Economists have pointed out the sharp contrast between the economic theory of pricing and lack of its application in practice. Public sector pricing theory recommends that prices be set equal to long-run marginal cost (e.g. long term incremental capital and running cost) so as to achieve an efficient allocation of resources. The optimal two-part tariff has both a fixed component (to recover capital cost) and a variable component (to meet the recurring costs). However, there are both theoretical and practical problems related with marginal cost pricing. Firstly, the assumptions on which the theory of allocative efficiency is based generally do not hold; and secondly, implementation may not be feasible. The earlier view of financing of Government expenditure through budgetary resource was justified on the ground that the benefit of pure public goods are expected to accrue to the society as a whole. Therefore, the marginal cost pricing principle that is generally applicable for the pricing of private goods and services could not be applied to public goods. Government 6 Oakland, W.H. 1987. “Theory of Public Goods.” In Handbook of Public Economics ed. Auerbach, A.J. and M. Feldstein, Vol. II, Amsterdam, North Holland: 485-536. 7 Burns, E. Michael and Walsh, Cliff. 1981. “Market Provision of Price-excludable Public Goods: A General Analysis”. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 89(11). 8 is expected to recover the cost either through taxes or public borrowings. The marginal cost pricing approach implies that in general (a) the marginal benefit to the society exceeds the marginal cost, and (b) the marginal benefits of financing the service is at least equal to the possible marginal benefits from other competing investments. The unit marginal cost to the society is the opportunity cost of allocating the resources. The marginal cost theory 8 requires that there should not be any external effects in consumption and production, and competitive forces should operate throughout the economy. None of these exist in practice. Services such as health and education have a profound, though intangible, effect on society and economy. Also equity and constitutional factors magnify the problems for marginal cost pricing, as well the lack of accurate information and data. “Free rider” problem may also exist for local public goods such as street lighting, defence, and law and order. Besides, if provisioning of services is related to willingness to pay, it will result in a very complex discriminatory fare structure. For goods and services that do not have any externalities, some percent of the average cost may be fixed as user charge. The services having positive externalities may have to be subsidized by the Government to some extent i.e. user charges may not help to recover the full cost. The positive externalities may be limited within the jurisdiction or may have a spill over effect outside the jurisdiction. Such services include education, health, and sanitation etc 9 . The Government has to provide some of the important services that fall in the category of merit goods. These include improved water supply, sanitation, and electricity services. These are associated with improving productivity and living standards in several ways. First, provision of these services has strong and direct links to improvement in health. Waterborne diseases in the developing world exact a high cost in terms of death, malnutrition, stunting, and reduced productivity. Electricity enables improved health service delivery. Access to these services improves education level in the developing world 10 . Millennium Declaration of the United Nations General Assembly 11 suggests that some of the targets for growth are infrastructure services such as electricity, transport, and telecommunications. These are widely acknowledged as the key factors for achieving improved health, education, income, and poverty goals. Methodology of the Study Given the growing importance of non-tax revenue in the fiscal structure and the increasing emphasis on the cost recovery through the imposition of ‘user charges’, this study at the outset proposes to examine the fiscal significance of the States own non-tax sources over a 8 This and the other theories related to fixing user charges are discussed in detail, later in chapter 3. Downing, Paul B. 1992. “The Revenue Potential of User Charges in Municipal Finance.” Public Finance Quarterly, Vol. 20 (4): 512-527. 10 Komives, Kristin - (et. al.). 2005. Water, Electricity, and the Poor: Who Benefits from Utility Subsidies. Directions in Development, Energy and Water Division, World Bank.Washington, D.C. 11 UN Millennium Project. 2005. Investing in development: A Practical Plan to Achieve the Millennium Development Goals. London Earthscan. Available at http://www.unmillenniumproject.org. 9 9 period of time. In doing so, it covers all the States, with special emphasis on 15 major States 12 . In addition to examining the trend rate, it estimates buoyancy of all the major non-tax sources and provides a comparative picture of all the States. To analyze the efforts of the States in collecting appropriate user charges for the services provided, the study presents an estimate of the revenue realized (RR) from services as percent of revenue expenditure (RE) incurred on providing these services. To facilitate comparison between RRi (revenue realized from the ith service) amongst the States, the study presents a normative approach to estimate ‘norms’ of RR for each of the services by using panel data models. To appraise the performance of the States in collecting RR for the select services, the study attempts to analyse difference between the actual and normative RR (estimated through the regression approach) for each of the select services. This is done by taking RR of a specific service as a function of related independent variables. Efforts have been made to identify the factors responsible for lack of growth of non-tax sources in the States. Policy imperatives are put forth for exploring the scope for rationalizing rate structures and thereby, improving the overall budgetary position of the States as well as efficiency in resource use. In doing so, the study takes into account the variations in the RR of select non-tax sources for each major State. Also, it looks into the issues related to delivery of services by the Government. Special emphasis is laid on analyzing user conveniences for some of the services, viz. education, health care, water supply, and roads and bridges. Sources of Data This study makes use of all available sources of data for the analysis of non-tax sources in Indian States. Primarily, the study uses data from Reserve Bank of India (RBI), State Budget Documents, Central Statistical Organization, Bureau of Economics and Statistics, the various State ministries dealing with different non-tax services etc. RBI presents a rich source of data on State finances. Due to various reasons regarding comparability, however, data on revenue from non-tax sources in RBI documents are not presented in sufficient details. Hence, this study uses RBI data to have a macro analysis only. For the purpose of disaggregated analysis of each of the minor heads of non-tax sources, as shown in Annexure A.1.1, the State budget documents are used. From these documents, we have collected details of the revenue and expenditure on non-tax sources for the select services, at a highly disaggregated level. Unfortunately, even in the budget documents, items such as lotteries, interests, departmental undertakings, etc. are not reflected correctly. Hence, necessary adjustments have been made, wherever required. 12 The major States include Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, Goa, Gujarat, Haryana, Karnataka, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Uttar Pradesh, Tamil Nadu and West Bengal. 10 In all, this study uses two major sources to collect the basic data for non-tax sources. These are given below: a. Time series data for the period 1993-94 to 2003-04 is collected from the various issues of the Reserve Bank of India titled Study of State Finances. Data pertains to States’ own tax revenue, non-tax revenue, revenue expenditure, and capital expenditure (at four digit level). It covers 15 major States under broad heads. b. Data for two points of time, i.e. the first three years of the study (1993-94 to 1995-96) and the last three years of the study (2001-02 to 2003-04) have been collected from the respective State Budget Documents for 15 major States for ten select services. The information is collected for all the components or the subheads at a four-digit level for all the selected non-tax sources. The effort has been to collect data relating to the base and current rates as well as data on other related variables for each of the non-tax sources. Scheme of Presentation The sequence of presentation of the Report is as follows: Chapter 2 analyses fiscal significance of States’ own non-tax sources. In doing so, it examines the role of various social and economic services in the budget. The next chapter delves into the theories of utility pricing. It presents a review of literature related to utility pricing. Chapter 4 presents estimates of revenue realised as a percent of revenue expenditure for the select general, social and economic services. These are based on, the data available from the RBI and also from the State budget documents. The chapter also puts forth norms for revenue realized (RR) based on regression technique using panel data models. Norms are presented for the select services. Using the benchmark of norms, efforts are made to present the gap in the actual and estimated RR for each service as well as for each State. The next chapter (chapter 5) presents areas of reforms in the structure of non-tax sources in the Indian States. Chapter 6 analyses issues related to procedures and delivery of services. Finally, chapter 7 presents a summary of conclusions and policy recommendations. 11 Annexure A.1.1 Classification of Non-tax Revenue in State Budgets Sources of Non-tax Revenue with Budget Heads in Indian State Government Accounts Sl. No. 1 2 2.1 2.2 2.3 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 24.1 24.2 24.3 Description Compulsory, requited payments to government Earmarked taxes Fines and penalties Police fees, fines and forfeitures Judicial fines and forfeitures Other fines and forfeitures Voluntary, unrequited payments to government Donations Unclaimed deposits and excess payments Voluntary, unrequited payments to government Revenue from assets Interest receipts Dividends from public undertakings Dividends from other investments Mineral concession fees, rents and royalties Public works (rents on buildings, hire charges for equipment, etc.) Housing Fishery rents Environmental, forestry and wildlife Major and medium irrigation projects (1) Minor irrigation projects (1) Petroleum Roads and Bridges (1) Revenue from regulated activity and sale of permits, goods and services General Services (2) Public service commission Police (except 055-103 above) Jails Stationery and printing Other administrative services Miscellaneous general services (excluding 0075-101, 0075-103) State lotteries Social Services Education, sports, art and culture Elementary education Secondary education University and higher education Budget Head 0055-103 0070-01102 Various 0075-101 0049 0050-101 0050-200 0853-102 0059 0216 0405-011 0406-02 0701 0702 0802 1054 0051 0055 0056 0058 0070 0075 0075-103 less 2075103 0202 0202-101 0202-102 0202-103 12 24.4 25 25.1 25.2 25.3 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 32.1 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 Technical education Medical and public health Urban health services Medical education, research and training Public health Family welfare Water supply and sanitation Urban development Information and publicity Labour and employment Social security and welfare Other social services Welfare of SC, ST and OBC Economic Services Crop husbandry Animal husbandry (3) Dairy development Fisheries (excluding 0405-011) Forestry (4) Plantations Food storages and warehousing Cooperation Other agricultural programme Land Reforms (5) Other rural development programmes Other special areas programmes Power (1) Village and small industries Non-ferrous mining and metallurgical industries (excluding 0853-102) Other industries Ports and lighthouses Civil aviation Road transport Other scientific research Tourism Civil supplies Other economic services 0202-02 0210 0210-01 0210-03 0210-04 0211 0215 0217 0220 0230 0235 0250 0250-102 0401 0403 0404 0405 0406-01 0407 0408 0425 0435 0506 0515 0575 0801 0851 0853 0875 1051 1053 1055 1425 1452 1456 1475 Notes: The Budget head numbers in the table are based on the Budget for Gujarat for 2005-06. There is some variation in items included in minor budget heads across States and years. (1): May include contra entries. (2): Head 0071 less head 2071, pertaining to pensions and retirement benefits, is omitted as being conceptually capital receipts. (3): Includes head 0403-110, Grants from the Indian Council of Agricultural Research, which should be netted out to calculate a State's own non-tax revenue. (4): Mainly consists of 0406-01, sale of timber and other forest produce. (5): Includes 0506-103, receipts from maintenance of land records. 13 2 Fiscal Significance of States’ Own Non-tax Sources Non-tax revenue is one of the constituents of the revenue receipts of the Indian States. In the decade of the nineties, States own non-tax revenue constituted between 13.7 and 17.7 percent of the total revenue receipts and between 9.2 and 13.1 percent of the total receipts of the States. These proportions have since then declined considerably. States own non-tax revenue as percent of the total revenue receipts is reported to be 12.1 percent and as percent of total receipts of the States as 2.9 1 percent in 2003-04. Non-tax revenue as a percentage of GSDP is an indicator of the efficiency in mobilization of these revenues in the total revenue receipts. While the proportion of States own non-tax revenue to GSDP in Indian States has varied between 1.5 and 2.4 percent over the years, it may be useful to note the non-tax mobilization by other countries in a comparative context. Data on non-tax revenue as a percentage of GDP 2 bring out the fact that Botswana has the highest ratio of the order of 29 percent in 1998. Countries like Singapore, Egypt and Iran having 10 percent non-tax revenue to GDP ratio can provide some useful lessons in non-tax revenue mobilization (Table 2.1). Composition and Trends in States’ Own Non-tax Revenues Trends in own non-tax revenue (Ontr) of the Indian States indicate that while there is an increase in absolute terms over the years, as percent to aggregate receipts, it has gradually declined from 11.6 percent in 1993-94 to 8.4 percent in 2002-03 and further to 2.9 percent in 2003-04 (Table 2.2). It has recorded a growth rate of only 7.9 percent per year 3 while 1 While in absolute terms the own non-tax revenues have gone up, the decline in the proportion is primarily due to a major increase in capital receipts of the states. 2 International Monetary Fund. 2006. Government Finance Statistics, June. Washington, D C. 3 The growth rate is estimated over a period of time by fitting the following relationship: R = abt, where b = (1+r), b is the value of growth character of R, and t varies from 1 to n. exhibiting buoyancy 4 of less than 1 over the period. On the other hand, although its share in total non-tax revenue increased marginally from 42.4 percent in 1993-94 to 42.7 percent in 2003-04, its contribution to current account receipts and GDP has gone down from about 14.8 percent and 2 percent in 1993-94, respectively to 12.1 percent and 1.5 percent in 2003-04, respectively. Also with respect to States own revenue, Sontr has exhibited a decline to 19.3 percent in 2003-04 as compared to 25.1 percent in 1993-94 (Table 2.2). In terms of contribution of own non-tax revenue to GSDP, some of the States indicate an increasing trend. Goa, for example, recorded Ontr of 5.7 percent of GSDP in 1993-94, which increased to 14.1 percent by the year 2001-02. However, it recorded a decline thereafter and rested at the level of 7.5 percent in 2003-04. This fall in the percentage share could, however, be attributed to a fall in the growth rate of Goa’s Ontr during the second time period, i.e. when period under consideration is bifurcated into two time periods, viz. 1993-94 to 199899 and 1999-00 to 2003-04, it is observed that Goa has witnessed a steep fall in growth rate of Ontr, from 39.9 percent during first time period to 5.5 percent during second time period. Consequently, the buoyancy of the Ontr declined from 1.8 to 0.7 between the two time periods resulting in the buoyancy value of 1.4 for the whole period, (i.e. 1993-94 to 2003-04). The three other States that have witnessed rising trend in the share of States’ Ontr to GSDP are Gujarat, Punjab and Tamil Nadu, whereas rest of the States exhibited a declining trend. Their average contribution to GSDP stood at about 2.5 percent, 4.3 percent and 1.1 percent per annum, respectively (Table 2.3). Over the period while Punjab has recorded an increase in Ontr at the rate of 17 percent per annum, it was 12.1 percent and 11.8 percent per annum in case of Gujarat and Tamil Nadu, respectively. Considering the growth rate and buoyancy between the two time periods, it may be observed that all the three States, (i.e. Gujarat, Punjab and Tamil Nadu) have witnessed a fall in growth rate to 4.1 percent, 18.3 percent and 10 percent, respectively in the second phase from 14 percent, 22.3 percent, and 10.9 percent per annum in the first phase. On the other hand, while Punjab and Tamil Nadu exhibited a rise in the buoyancy of States Ontr, it declined in Gujarat. All the three States registered buoyancy in the Ontr for the whole period. All the other major States have exhibited a gradual decline in their share of Ontr to GSDP from the level that was obtained in the early 1990’s. The States, which exhibited fall of more than half in the ratio, during the period, are Haryana, Maharashtra, West Bengal and Madhya Pradesh. These States occupy the lowest rank in terms of Ontr--GSDP ratio. Even when all non-special category States (includes all major States and three States of Chhattisgarh, Jharkhand and NCT Delhi), are analysed, it shows a decline in the Ontr from 1.6 percent in 1993-94 to 1.3 percent in the year 2003-04, recording a growth rate of 7.5 percent per annum with rather less buoyant (0.7) Ontr. 4 Buoyancy coefficient is a measure of the degree of responsiveness to changes in income. It is expressed as: δ = (dY/dX)*X/Y and estimated by following relationship: ln Y = α + β ln X where X is independent variable (income) and Y is dependent variable (tax revenue). 15 Components of States’ Own Non-tax Revenue (Ontr) Revenue from interests, dividends and profits, general services, economic services and social services; forms key constituents of the Ontr of the Indian States. As it may be observed from Table 2.2 that while States’ Ontr as percent to total non-tax revenue has increased only marginally over the years; its share has declined as a percent of aggregate receipts as well as percent of current account receipts & GDP. However, this decline can be attributed to the slowdown in the rate of growth of components of Ontr, particularly, revenue earned from interest receipts and social services. For an overall analysis of States’ Ontr, these sources are analysed below in detail in respect of their contribution to revenue in each State. The interest receipts component of States’ Ontr is often misleading in nature as it merely denotes book transfers and that too internal transfer from other States Government departments. Apart from being so, interest receipts grew only at 7.1 percent per annum and therefore create sluggishness in the growth of non-tax revenue in the States. The average rate of return on capital invested in the State Electricity Boards, which accounts for the bulk of the State investment in public sector undertakings, had been persistently negative as they defaulted in interest payment and loan repayment regularly5 . Their contribution to the all-States’ Ontr went down steadily from 30.4 percent in 1993-94 to 22.6 percent in 2003-04 (Table 2.2). Revenue from dividends and profits arise from the State Government’s investment in the shares of co-operative institutions, statutory corporations, Government companies and other joint stock companies. However, in majority of cases no dividend is received due to nonavailability of surpluses or due to losses. Though dividends and profits exhibit an impressive growth rate of 16.4 percent per annum, its share as percent to States’ Ontr has always remained less than 1, except in the year 2003-04 in which case its percentage share increased to 1.02 percent (Table 2.2). Consequently, the share of this source is quite negligible. Thus, the above two sources of non-tax revenues, i.e. interest receipts, profits and dividends, can hardly be relied upon for the growth of non-tax revenue sources. Other components of States’ Ontr are recoveries from services rendered by the Government, which broadly may be grouped as (1) general services, (2) social services, and (3) economic services. About two-third of the States’ Ontr accrues from these services. The share of these services has shown a rising trend during the past few years, not so much due to the absolute rise in this source, but because of the decline in other sources. Among these three services, the share of economic services has remained highest, while social services have contributed the least. Social services and economic services have exhibited an upward trend with respect to States’ Ontr, while general services have shown considerable fluctuations. Economic services, which were contributing about 44.5 percent to States’ Ontr in 1993-94, had fallen considerably 5 See Government of India. Report of the Eleventh Finance Commission. New Delhi. p.47. 16 in 1997-98 to 34.1 percent. However, this share reverted and reached around its initial level by 2003-04 (Table 2.2). Among these services, the general services have been the least consistent, followed by social services and economic services. As percent to aggregate receipts and GSDP, all three services have shown decline during the period from 2.2 percent to 0.7 percent and from 0.38 percent to 0.37 percent, respectively for general services, from 0.7 percent to 0.3 percent and 0.12 percent to 0.13 percent, respectively for social services and from 5.2 percent to 1.2 percent and 0.9 percent to 0.7 percent in case of economic services (Table 2.2). On the other hand, as percent to current account receipts and States’ own revenue, while both general services and economic services have shown a declining trend over the years, the social services have exhibited an upward trend although its share is minimum in States own revenue that has varied from 1.5 percent in 1993-94 to 1.7 percent in 2003-04. As percent to total non-tax revenue also, while general services and social services displayed a rise in their share (from 8.0 percent and 2.5 percent, respectively in 1993-94 to 10.5 percent and 3.7 percent, respectively in 2003-04), economic services exhibited a modest decline from 18.8 percent in 1993-94 to 18.5 percent in 2003-04 (Table 2.2). Receipts from General Services Receipts from general services originates from (a) public service commission, (b) police, (c) jails, (d) supplies and disposals, (e) stationary and printing, (f) public works, (g) other administrative services, (h) contribution and recoveries towards pension and other retirement benefits, and (i) other miscellaneous general services. The revenue from general services as percent to States’ Ontr has shown downward trend over the years. While its yield in 1993-94, in absolute terms, was only Rs 2,947.23 crore, it increased to Rs.9,372.43 crore in 2003-04, registering growth rate of 6.4 percent per annum. Also, the share in Ontr increased to the level of 24.5 percent in 2003-04 from 18.9 percent in 1993-94, after reaching a peak of 33.3 percent in the year 1995-96. As a result it indicates lack of buoyancy (0.5) (Table 2.2). On classifying the States according to the level of income, i.e. into the category of high income States, middle income States, and low income States, it may be observed that the average percentage share of general services in States’ Ontr is highest for high-income States (31.2 percent) and lowest for middle-income States (14.8 percent). The share of low-income States is 17.4 percent (Table 2.3). It may also be observed that while high-income and lowincome States exhibited a declining trend over the years, middle-income States exhibited a rising trend. However, in terms of growth rate and buoyancy, in middle-income States it has been growing at the highest rate (18.3 percent) while remaining buoyant for the period under consideration. On the other hand, in high-income States it has been growing at 7.3 percent per annum while in the low-income States it exhibited a declining growth rate of -5.0 percent, exhibiting buoyancy value of 0.7 and -0.6, respectively (Table 2.3). Taking two time period under consideration, viz. 1993-94 to 1998-99 and 1999-00 to 2003-04, it may be noted that in all three income categories of States, there has been an improvement in growth rate of general receipts in second time period as compared to the level reached during first time period. The 17 same is true with buoyancy values. A rising trend in revenue from general services has been displayed in 11 of the 15 major States while the remaining 4, i.e. Haryana, Orissa, Rajasthan, and Uttar Pradesh, recorded a declining trend. A comparative analysis across the States and amongst the highincome States indicates that the revenue from general services in Punjab has exhibited the highest average share (55.9 percent) in States’ Ontr. It increased from 16.3 percent in 1993-94 to whooping 55.6 percent in 2003-04. However, Punjab’s maximum share in States’ Ontr was 80.2 percent in 1994-95 and lowest share of 8.6 percent in 1996-97. Over the years revenue from general services in Punjab has grown at the rate of 27.3 percent while exhibiting a buoyancy of 2.4 (Table 2.3). In 1993-94, Haryana contributed about 64.4 percent of general revenue to States’ Ontr (which was the highest share amongst the States). However, it declined over the years and Haryana contributed roughly half of its initial share (about 30.5 percent) in 2003-04; whereas Punjab had the largest share of about 55.6 percent. Nevertheless, on an average, Haryana contributes about 51.1 percent per annum to the States’ Ontr. Amongst the high-income States, on the other hand, Goa has been the least consistent State contributing on an average about 35.8 percent to States Ontr. The revenue from general services in Goa was only 2.8 percent of States’ Ontr in the first two years, which varied between 36 and 56.7 percent. Middle-income States, on the other hand, showed a rising trend over the years. In the year 1993-94, Kerala’s revenue from general services as percent of States’ Ontr was highest amongst the middle-income States. This, however, declined over the years and Karnataka’s share of revenue from general services to the States’ Ontr was the highest (60.3 percent) in the year 2003-04; though the average contribution of Kerala’s share remained higher than the Karnataka’s share (Table2.3). In Kerala it was contributing about 27.8 percent to States’ Ontr in 1993-94, which increased to 38.1 percent in 2003-04; rising at the rate of 11.7 percent per annum while remaining perfectly elastic for the whole period. Average contribution of revenue from general services to GSDP stood at 0.3 percent over the years. On the other hand, Karnataka was contributing about 9.5 percent to States’ Ontr, which increased to 27.3 percent in 2002-03. However, it almost doubled in 2003-04 and stood at 60.3 percent. In Karnataka, revenue from general services has been rising at the rate of 24.2 percent per annum, exhibiting the buoyancy of 1.7 for the whole period. The rate of growth and buoyancy for the second time period was 74 percent and 7.2, respectively, which was much higher than the first time period (12.2 percent and 0.8, respectively). Its average contribution to GSDP stood at 0.3 percent per annum. It must be noted that it is the State amongst middleincome States, which has been the least consistent over the years. The rest of the middle-income States, viz. Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu and West Bengal have contributed on an average about 5.5 percent, 16.3 percent and 25.5 percent, respectively to States’ Ontr. However, as percent to GSDP, their respective share was 0.1 percent, 0.2 percent and 0.1 percent, respectively (Table 2.3). 18 Three of low-income States have shown a rise in their share over the years while the rest have exhibited a decline. However, in three States it has exhibited the declining trend in their revenue from general services. Amongst the low-income States, in Uttar Pradesh revenue from general services has been the highest contributor to the States’ Ontr. Its average share in States’ revenue stood at 26.3 percent per annum. Its share was almost 50 percent of States’ Ontr in 1993-94, which increased to 55 percent in 1995-96, and declined thereafter to 12.5 percent in 2003-04. Thus, it has shown high variation amongst the low-income States. The State with second highest average share in States’ Ontr is Rajasthan, which contributed about 22.8 percent per annum. Rajasthan is followed by States like Bihar, Orissa and Madhya Pradesh. Their contribution to own non-tax receipts stood at 15 percent, 9.2 percent and 8.4 percent per annum, respectively. In the low-income States, revenue from general services constituted 0.4 percent of GSDP, where Rajasthan has contributed highest (0.7 percent), followed by Uttar Pradesh, Madhya Pradesh, Bihar and Orissa (Table 2.3). Receipts from Social Services Revenue contribution of social services was least, although it grew at the highest rate among other services - at 14.5 percent annually and these receipts were buoyant (1.2) at allStates level. As percent of States’ Ontr, receipts from these services increased from 5.9 percent in 1993-94 to 8.6 percent in 2003-04 (Table 2.2). Amongst the three income-category States, viz. high, middle and low income category, the share of social services in Ontr was highest in middle-income category States (9.1 percent), followed by high-income (5.6 percent) and low-income (4.5 percent) States in 1993-94. However, by the year 2003-04 low-income States become the highest contributor (contributing about 12 percent), followed by middle-income States (10.6 percent) and high-income States (7.1 percent). In terms of growth rate and buoyancy, not only all the three income categories exhibited a growth rate of almost 14 percent but also remained buoyant for the period under consideration. Amongst major States, revenue from social services in West Bengal has contributed the most to its Ontr (about 19.2 percent) in 1993-94, followed by Kerala (13.0 percent), Tamil Nadu (12.5 percent), and Punjab (11.0 percent). The States that made the least contribution are Madhya Pradesh (3.7 percent), Uttar Pradesh (3.7 percent), Bihar (3.5 percent) and Haryana (3.0 percent) (Table 2.3). The rest of the States made contributions in the range of 5 percent to 7 percent, except Goa, which contributed around 9.5 percent of the States’ Ontr. On the other hand in 1993-94 revenue from social services as percent of GSDP was highest in Goa among high-income States as well as in all other States. Amongst middle-income States, the percentage share in Kerala (0.16) was the highest while it was Rajasthan (0.24) amongst low-income States. Taking revenue of social services from all-States as percent of GSDP into account, one finds that the proportion is meager, just about 0.12 percent, whereas in all non-special States it stood at 0.10 percent. This implies that the share in all special category States is not more than 0.02 percent of GSDP. 19 In the year 2003-04, on the other hand, Bihar is the State whose revenue from social services as percent of States’ Ontr was highest (28.1 percent) followed by Tamil Nadu (22.8 percent); whereas as percent of GSDP, Goa has the highest ratio accounting about 0.8 percent of GSDP. Seven out of 15 major States contribute about 10 percent to 16 percent of States’ Ontr. Remaining States show this percentage varying between 2 percent and 6 percent (Table 2.3). In all non-special category States, receipts from social services increased from Rs.88,587 lakh in 1993-94 to Rs.307,543 lakh in 2003-04, registering a growth rate of 14.2 percent per annum (whereas exhibiting fall in rate between the two time periods from 15.1 percent during first time period to 9.5 percent during the second time period). Its share in States’ Ontr have exhibited upward trend, rising from 6.0 percent in 1993-94 to 8.8 percent in 2003-04 (Table 2.3). The buoyancy coefficient has also remained more than 1 between the two time periods and over the period. Receipts from Economic Services The revenue from economic services, in absolute terms, at the all-States level increased from Rs.6,921.13 crore in 1993-94 to 16,525.45 crore in 2003-04, while growing at the rate of 8.4 percent per annum. However, as percent to States’ Ontr, it exhibited a modest decline from 44.5 percent in 1993-94 to 43.3 percent in 2003-04 (Table 2.2). On an average, 38.7 percent is drawn from economic services as percent of all-States’ Ontr. In fact, revenue from low-income States contributed the most (52.2 percent) over the years, showing signs of increasing share in States’ Ontr (from 49.5 percent in 1993-94 to 50.5 percent in 2003-04). In high-income and middle-income States there has been a decline to 38.8 and 33.7 percent, respectively in 2003-04 from the level of 38.9 and 38.7 percent, respectively in 1993-94 (Table 2.3). However, as a percent of GSDP all three-income categories showed a decline in their share over the period. In terms of growth rate and buoyancy, in high-income States it was 9.3 percent per annum and 0.8, respectively followed by middle-income States (9.7 percent per annum and 0.8, respectively) and low-income States (1.2 percent per annum and 0.2, respectively) (Table 2.3). Amongst the low-income States, although the average share of revenue from economic services in Sontr has been significant in Madhya Pradesh followed by that of Orissa and Bihar; in all three States it exhibited a declining trend during the period. In Madhya Pradesh revenue from economic services contributed about 74.9 percent of States’ Ontr in 1993-94, which increased further to 84.2 percent by 2003-04. This was 62 percent and 61.3 percent, respectively in Orissa (Table 2.3). Contribution from economic services to the States’ Ontr was highest in Bihar. It contributed about 90.1 percent in States’ Ontr in 1993-94. But this declined drastically to 38.1 percent in 2003-04. Due to the declining growth rate (-16.3 percent per annum) over the years Bihar’s contribution was on an average about 62.8 percent to States’ Ontr. It has also shown enormous variations among the low-income States. 20 On the other hand, in three of middle-income States, the revenue from economic services has exhibited an upward trend over the years. In four out of five middle-income States, it has contributed more than 35 percent of the States’ Ontr. It may be observed that the share of revenue from economic services in States’ Ontr is highest in Kerala, contributing on an average 43.2 percent per annum, while growing at the rate of 4 percent per annum. However, in Karnataka it has been growing at the fastest rate (12.2 percent per annum); contributing about 37.7 percent on an average over the years while remaining highly buoyant for the whole period. Also, the State exhibited least consistency over the years as compared to other States under middle-income category. In the high-income States, revenue from economic services has exhibited the rising trend only in Haryana and Gujarat. Their average contributions to States’ Ontr were 28.0 and 33.4 percent, respectively, while growing at the rate of 9.4 and 14 percent per annum, respectively (Table 2.3). In Goa, the share has remained highest over the years followed by Maharashtra, Gujarat, and Haryana. Its share was 85.4 percent of States’ Ontr in 1993-94 which increased to about 88 percent by 2003-04, (on an average it contributed about 56.4 percent to States’ Ontr), growing at the rate of 19.8 percent per annum. In Punjab, the share stood at 54 percent of States’ Ontr in 1993-94, which declined to 18.6 percent in 1998-99. However, it declined considerably by the year 2003-04 and reached the level of 10.7 percent of Ontr, contributing on an average 16 percent to Sontr. Because of high fluctuations, it has been the least consistent State among the high-income category States. Components of Social Services The major items that fall under this service are: (a) Education, sports, arts and culture, (b) Medical, public health, and Family welfare, (c) Water supply and sanitation, (d) Housing, (e) Urban Development, (f) Labour and employment, (g) Social security and welfare, and (h) Other social services. The share of these components in social services in the beginning of the period under consideration and at the end of the period can be seen in the Exhibit 2.2. Amongst these components of social services, initially the share of revenue from medical, public health and family welfare as percent to revenue from social services was the highest. However, by the end of the period under consideration revenue from education, sports, arts and culture becomes the chief contributor. Also, the revenue from urban development and water supply and sanitation were the other fast growing components of social services. All these components constitute the major portion of receipts from social services for all-States. However, the revenue from each service varies from one State to another. The relative importance of these select activities and changes in their relative share in social services for all 15 major States, during the year 1993-94 and 2003-04, are shown in Tables 2.4 to 2.7. Education, arts, sports and culture The substantial part of budgeted non-tax receipts under this head comes from secondary 21 education and most of the receipts are accounted for by general and technical education. However, the share of general education has declined over the years, from 84.4 percent in 1993-94 to 58.1 percent in 2003-04 while the share of technical education has increased substantially from only 9.4 percent to 37.3 percent. Despite the active involvement of the private sector in most areas of education and research in India for decades, Government still plays a key role in the sector. It runs core institutions offering general education at primary, secondary and higher levels. It has also a dominant presence in almost all areas of professional and technical education including the subjects like art, culture and drama. Government exercises control over almost all the regulatory functions that need to be performed for ensuring the quality of education. Revenue receipts from education accrue mainly from user charges levied for services directly supplied by State run institutions. Another source of non-tax revenues are the fees and penalties arising out of the regulatory functions performed by Government in the field of education. Revenue from education, sports, arts and culture is one of the major components of revenue from social services. It constitutes, on an average, about 26.5 percent of social services in all-States. Over the years, revenue from this sector increased from Rs.219.4 crore in 1993-94 to Rs. 1,033.1 crore in 2003-04 (for all-States). This revenue source had a growth rate of 17.5 percent per annum and remained buoyant for the whole period for each category of States. As a percent to receipts from social services, it increased from 24 percent in 1993-94 to 31.5 percent in 2003-04. However, during the same time period the receipts from education, sports, arts and culture in all the States other than special category States, increased from 24.0 percent to 30.1 percent; growing at 16.8 percent per annum (Table 2.4). It shows that the share of all special category States in revenue from education, sports, arts and culture is quite insignificant. Amongst the major States, revenue from education, sports, arts and culture in highincome States exhibited a declining trend over the years. However, the other two categories displayed an upward trend. It is observed that the share in low-income States increased substantially over the years, while in high-income States it has increased only marginally. The share of the middle-income States’ reverted to 30.5 percent in 2003-04. This had initially declined to 24.1 percent of revenue from social services in 1998-99 from 31.6 percent in 199394. On the other hand, the average contribution of revenue from education, sports, arts and culture as percent to revenue from social services has been highest in middle-income States (32.1 percent). This was 30.9 percent for low-income States and only 17.2 percent for highincome States. In terms of growth rate and buoyancy, the growth rate of receipts from education, sports, arts and culture has been highest in low-income States (20.6 percent), along with highest buoyancy (1.9). Middle-income States and high-income States had a growth rate and buoyancy of 16.7 percent & 1.3; and 11.3 percent & 1.0, respectively (Table 2.4). Of the 15 major States, ten contributed to the rise in all-States’ revenue from education, sports, arts and culture. Of these, four were high-income States (Goa, Gujarat, Maharashtra and 22 Punjab) and four were low income States (Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan & Uttar Pradesh). Only two middle-income States (Kerala and West Bengal) showed an increasing trend. In 1993-94, revenue from education, sports, arts and culture in 8 States contributed more than 20 percent to social services; whereas in 2003-04 two more States joined the group. As percent to States’ Ontr, the contribution of majority of the States has been less than 2 percent over the period. On an average, revenue from education, sports, arts and culture was highest in Kerala, followed by Uttar Pradesh and Tamil Nadu, whereas the least was collected in Goa, Maharashtra, Punjab and Madhya Pradesh etc. Also, while the all three income categories exhibited a rise in their share in Sontr for the period under consideration, the average contribution was highest for middle-income States followed by low-income States and high-income States (Table 2.4). In this analysis of revenue from education, sports, arts and culture as a percent of GSDP, it has been observed that the percentage share of this component of social services in GSDP in all States has risen from 0.03 percent in 1993-94 to 0.04 percent in 2003-04. The same trend is seen in case of all non-special category States. Amongst the major States, in 1993-94 the share in middle-income States has remained higher than in other two categories. However, in the later period it is the low-income category States whose share in GSDP was the highest (0.07 percent) (Table 2.4). Medical, public health and family welfare Non-tax revenues accruing from the health sector are accounted for from rural and urban health services, medical education and public health. The revenue from this sector indicates that the major part is drawn from the urban health services. In 1993-94, this revenue contributed about 87.8 percent of health services. However, this declined over the years and stood at about 71 percent in 2003-04. Also, share of public health services was 6.4 percent in 1993-94, which increased to 14.6 percent by the year 2003-04. Medical, public health and family welfare is another significant component of social services. However, revenue from this sector in all-States has exhibited a declining trend over the years. As a percent of revenue from social services, its share declined to half, i.e. from 34.9 percent in 1993-94 to 17.7 percent in 2003-04, contributing on an average 25.1 percent per annum. In all-States, it has been rising at the rate of 9.1 percent per annum, while remaining less buoyant for the whole period (Table 2.5). It exhibited declining growth rate from 8.0 percent in first time period to 4.9 percent per annum in the second time period. On the other hand, as percent to States’ own non-tax receipts, revenue from health services in all-States showed an upward trend with share declining from 2.1 percent in 1993-94 to 1.5 percent in 2003-04 (Table 2.5). It may be noted that as percent to revenue from social services, the revenue from health services exhibited a declining trend in all the three income categories; whereas as percent to States’ own non-tax receipts, it registered an upward trend only in low-income States. Their average contribution to social services stood at 29.1 percent, 30.0 percent and 16.0 percent; 23 respectively while as percent to States’ Ontr it was 1.5 percent, 2.9 percent and 1.3 percent; rising over the years at the rate of 7.9 percent, 8.9 percent and 8.6 percent per annum, respectively (Table 2.5). State wise analysis indicates that each of the major States demonstrated a declining trend over the years, whereas Goa (high-income States), Andhra Pradesh (middle-income States) and Bihar (low-income States) showed utmost variation with respect to social services. The average share of revenue from medical, public health and family welfare in social services was highest in West Bengal (59.4 percent) amongst the States. It has been rising at the rate of 5.2 percent per annum while exhibiting negative growth rate and buoyancy between the two time periods. It is followed by States like Punjab, Maharashtra, and Gujarat with the average share of 38.8 percent, 32.8 percent and 32.7 percent, respectively. On the other hand, as a percent of States’ Ontr, the highest average share was 8.3 percent in West Bengal. A rise in the share of receipts from health services as percent to States’ Ontr is seen only in five States, viz. Haryana, Maharashtra, Bihar, Madhya Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh. As percent to GSDP, revenue from medical, public health and family welfare in allStates constituted only 0.02 percent in 2003-04 and it was never more than 0.04 percent for the period under consideration. There has been a fall in this revenue in every State except in Goa where it has increased from 0.06 percent in 1993-94 to 0.08 percent in 2003-04. In no State has the share of medical, public health and family welfare as percent to GSDP crossed the mark of 1 percent level. This shows that the revenue from this service forms very minuscule part of GSDP due to the nature of service, which is highly subsidized (Table 2.5). Urban development In all-States, revenue from urban development contributed substantially to social services. Its share as percent to social services increased to 13.5 percent in 2003-04 from mere 3.1 percent in 1993-94, while growing at the rate of 20.5 percent per annum (Table 2.6). Among different income category States, the average share of high-income States in revenue from social services has been the highest (about 11.9 percent) followed by middle-income States (6.3 percent) and low-income States (1.2 percent). However, all three income-categories exhibited a rise in revenue from urban development as a percent of revenue from social services. While in high-income States and middle-income States, this increased from 6.6 percent and 1.3 percent (1993-94), respectively to 21.3 percent and 19.0 percent (2003-04), respectively; in low-income States it has increased by only 0.5 percent, from 1.2 percent to 1.6 percent for the same period (Table 2.6). This trend is due to the relationship of this service with the stage of economic development of the State. Over the years, share of receipts from urban development in both States’ Ontr and GSDP has risen in high, middle and low-income States. In terms of consistency, it has been found to be least consistent in middle-income States with respect to all three elements: as percent of social services, as percent of State Ontr and as percent of GSDP. However, in terms of growth rate and buoyancy, it may be observed that in low-income States it has recorded the highest growth rate (23.9 percent), followed by high-income (22.8 percent) and middle-income 24 States (11.1 percent). However, the buoyancy was highest in high-income States (2.0) and the lowest in middle-income States (0.9). Low-income States showed the buoyancy of the order of 1.98 (Table 2.6). Urban development in Haryana has been the main contributor to social services revenue. On an average it has contributed 31.5 percent to social services. Its share in 1993-94 was 7.7 percent. This increased to about 50 percent in 1997-98, but declined to 32.8 percent by the year 2002-03. However, within one year, its share again rose to 53.9 percent of social services. Due to these high fluctuations, Haryana has been least consistent among the highincome States. The other least consistent States are Gujarat and Maharashtra. Another noticeable feature about Haryana is that during first time period, (i.e. 1993-94 to 1998-99), revenue from urban development has been growing at the remarkable rate of about 95 percent whereas during the second phase the growth rate declined to 21.7 percent, recording growth rate of 39.6 percent per annum for the entire period. This source has remained highly buoyant in Haryana as compared to other high-income States (Table 2.6). On the other hand, Karnataka and Tamil Nadu are the middle-income States, which have shown maximum variations in revenue from urban development. While in Karnataka the share was 0.6 percent of social services in 1993-94, it increased to 47.9 percent in 1995-96 but declined thereafter to 1.9 percent in 2003-04. Whereas its share in Tamil Nadu was 0.7 percent in 1993-94, it increased to 40.8 percent by the end of the period. On the whole the growth rate in the middle-income States was 11.1 percent per annum (Table 2.6). Thus, the revenue from urban development in high-income States is highly responsive to change in GSDP and these States’ share in social services revenue is the highest. The share of low-income States is highly consistent (both as percent to social services and as percent to GSDP) and is growing at the highest rate per annum. However, in the share of middle-income States it has witnessed considerable fluctuations. Water supply and sanitation Though the share of revenue from water supply and sanitation in social services in allStates was negligible during the initial period, it contributed about 12.3 percent of social services in 2003-04. In absolute terms, the revenue from this source increased to Rs.40,350 lakh in 2003-04 from negligible amount in 1993-94. On an average, its share in social services has been 10.6 percent. The State in which revenue from water supply and sanitation contributed the most is Goa followed by States like Rajasthan and Orissa. The average contribution of these States during the period was 67.4 percent, 57 percent and 23.3 percent, respectively (Table 2.7). Also, these were the States with high inconsistency. Considering the high, middle and low income categories States, on an average, the percentage share of revenue from water supply and sanitation in social services was maximum in low-income States (20.2 percent) followed by high-income (9.8 percent) and middle-income States (2.2 percent). Also, in terms of consistency of revenue, the low-income States were least consistent; middle-income States were highly consistent. However, in terms of their share as 25 percent to GSDP, there has been high variation in high-income States while it was least in middle-income States. Growth rate and buoyancy for the period 1995-96 to 2003-04 has been highest for highincome States, 16.5 percent and 1.7, respectively; followed by middle-income and low-income States 6 (Table 2.7). Goa contributed highest share amongst the high-income States. It grew at the rate of about 19.3 percent per annum. In Punjab, its share has also been quite significant in this income category. Water supply and sanitation has, on an average, contributed 14.3 percent to revenue from social services. Its share was about 25.3 percent in 2003-04, which increased from 4.7% in 1993-94. In Punjab, however, revenue from this source has been rising at a much higher rate as compared to Goa, at about 29.4 percent per annum and a buoyancy of 2.9. In case of middle-income States, the average share of Andhra Pradesh was significant, although it declined from 8.4 percent to 2.5 percent over the years. The scenario was the same in the low-income States of Rajasthan and Orissa. Revenue from water supply and sanitation in West Bengal as percent of social services stood at 6.7 percent in 2003-04. This was only 3.2 percent in 1995-96. In West Bengal it exhibited a rising trend over the years; and has been growing at the rate of 25.2 percent per annum, though there has been a high variation during the period under consideration. Components of Economic Services The revenue from economic services comprise receipts from (a) Crop husbandry, (b) Animal husbandry, (c) Fisheries, (d) Forestry and wild life, (e) Co-operation, (f) Other agricultural and rural programmes, (g) Major and medium irrigation, (h) Minor irrigation, (i) Village and small scale industries, (j) Industries, (k) Plantations, (l) Power, (m) Petroleum, (n) Ports and Light Houses, (0) Road Transport, (p) Tourism and, (q) Others. Amongst the major constituents of economic services, the share of industries & forestry and wildlife was the highest. On the other hand, revenue trend of forestry and wildlife has exhibited the highest variability. There were also fluctuations in revenue from power, major and medium irrigation projects and roads and bridges. All these components together constitute more than 75 percent of economic services. Exhibit 2.3 shows the percentage share of each of select component of economic services for the years 1993-94 & 2003-04. Forestry and wildlife Forestry is the second largest land-use in the country following agriculture. It provides livelihood to an estimated 275 million people in rural areas, which includes a high portion of tribals and poorest and most vulnerable groups in society. Under forestry, revenue is mainly realized from forests on Government lands. Forest produce is directly exploited and sold by the Government. Revenue from different items from forests by Government is derived principally from timber, followed by firewood and charcoal, 6 Growth rate and buoyancy could not be calculated for the entire period for all states in want of data. 26 eucalyptus, driftwood, bamboo, sandalwood, grass and sandal oil. Government exercises a regulatory function by levying fines for violations of rules on both Government and private land and collecting permit and license fees. In case of private forests, revenue is earned through fees levied under the Tree Preservation Act, seignorage on reserved trees, fees for activities like stamping logs etc. Also, in order to conserve biodiversity in the animal world in a natural environment, wildlife is protected by reserving land for National Parks and Sanctuaries and protecting them. Forests account for around 67 million hectares, i.e. nearly 20.6 percent of the land area in India. In addition, there is another 2.5 percent of land in the country under tree cover. Thus 23 percent of the country is under forest and tree cover. Bulks of the forests in the country are located in the Western Himalayas, East Deccan, North Eastern region and the Western Ghats. The inter-state distribution of forests is quite skewed and therefore, the revenue from forestry and wildlife may vary from State to State as one State may have huge area under forestry and wild life, (e.g. Madhya Pradesh) while another State may have a very thin forest cover area, (e.g. Bihar). Amongst the three income-categories States, the middle-income States have maximum forest cover area. Then comes the low-income and high-income States. As a percent of revenue from economic services, it is maximum in middle-income States (23.7 percent) as compared to other two categories. The major source of revenue of forest departments is from auctioning and sale of timber, which is a Government monopoly. However, except Bihar, almost all the States exhibited a declining trend in their receipts from forestry and wildlife. According to a Supreme Court ruling, silviculture and timber exploitation cannot be undertaken by a State in a forest zone until it has in place “scientific” work plans covering the zone. The failure of some States to draw up work plans is the chief cause of severely declining forest revenues. The decline is particularly marked in States like Orissa and Uttar Pradesh. Though States like Orissa and Madhya Pradesh (in the low-income category) account for the maximum forest cover, nearly 37.3 and 31 percent of their geographical area, respectively, it is State of Kerala whose average revenue from forest and wildlife as percent of revenue from economic services is highest (59.4 percent) (Table 2.8). All-States’ revenue from forestry and wildlife as percent to States’ Ontr has declined over the years, (from 9.6 percent in 1993-94 to 5.1 percent in 2003-04). To this, the share in low-income States is highest (12 percent) followed by middle-income (8.2 percent) and highincome (1.8 percent) States. The average contribution from forestry and wild life in Madhya Pradesh is the highest (27.7 percent). The revenue in West Bengal was least consistent over the period, contributing 7.9 percent on an average. In 1993-94, Madhya Pradesh was the State with highest share in States’ Ontr (35.1 percent). It maintained its position even in the year 2003-04, contributing 33.6 percent to States’ Ontr. The next big contributor is Kerala (Table 2.8). As percent to GSDP, on the other hand, the average revenue from forest and wildlife stood at 0.25 percent in low-income States while it was 0.11 percent and 0.05 percent in case of middle-income and high-income States, respectively. In no State the average share 27 constitutes 1 percent of GSDP during the period. In terms of growth rate and buoyancy, 7 out of 15 major States exhibited a negative growth rate and buoyancy value (Table 2.8). Irrigation Irrigation projects are important national assets, created by pumping in huge investments, whose benefits cannot be evaluated in terms of direct financial returns. They generate social benefits in the form of better health and hygienic standards, higher literacy, better habitats etc., culminating in overall better standards of life, particularly in neglected rural communities, leading to higher productivity of water and land and human resources. Based on the area irrigated, these irrigation projects have been classified by the Central Government as major, medium and minor. Those with ayacuts above 10,000 hectares are treated as major projects, those with ayacuts between 2,000 hectares and 10,000 hectares are treated as medium projects and others are classified as minor projects. Minor irrigation projects irrigating areas less than 4 hectares have been placed under the management of taluk panchayats and those irrigating areas between 4 hectares and 40 hectares are managed by zila panchayats. The financial returns from irrigation in 15 States shows that there was a net loss of Rs.577.10 million in the form of interest on capital 7 . This was mainly because the approach towards irrigation works was based on commercial norms. However, the rainy season lasts for a short spell of 90 to 100 days over most parts of India. It is not possible to have either productive or protective irrigation without storage reservoirs. Once this realization dawned on policymakers, a sea change in irrigation development was seen in India only after the advent of storage based irrigation projects. Rural and agricultural water use has wide variations across the States. Over the years the revenue from irrigation are puzzling--increasing but not up to the mark 8 . Nevertheless, as far as revenue from irrigation across the States is concerned, there has been an increase in revenue from 9 States amongst the 15 major States; 8 States showed an increase in revenue from irrigation as percent of revenue from economic services while 9 States reported an increase as percent to States’ Ontr. Between 1993-94 and 2003-04, receipts from irrigation system (total of major, medium and minor irrigation system) for all-States increased by about 112.1 percent, while increasing 7 Government of India. 1972. Report of the Second Irrigation Commission. New Delhi. Important reasons include political problems related to cost recovery from farmers, especially in years of poor agricultural performance, poor water delivery management by irrigation departments, poor state of maintenance of irrigation works, inaccuracy of published technical data on these works and allegedly widespread corruption in irrigation departments, particularly in the case of new irrigation projects. An additional problem is infrequent revision of water rates in most states due to their political sensitivity and thus revenue from irrigation system has not been significant nor have they led to any improvement in the financial performance of the states. The allround deterioration in the financial performance of irrigation projects is stark and nearly universal. See for details supra chapter 6. 8 28 at the rate of 6.8 percent per annum over the years. On the other hand, in case of major and medium irrigation it increased by 121 percent and in minor irrigation it showed an increase to the extent of 59.2 percent. However, as percent to revenue from economic services at allStates’ level, revenue irrigation projects had exhibited a mild decline, from 7.95 percent in 1993-94 to 7.1 percent in 2003-04 (Table 2.9). To this decline revenue from middle-income States have added the most, while high-income and low-income States exhibited a rising trend. The same trend is observed for irrigation revenue as percent of States’ Ontr. While in middleincome States it exhibited a sharp decline from 8.9 percent of economic services and 3.4 percent of States’ Ontr in 1993-94 to 2.4 percent and 0.8 percent, respectively in 2003-04. On the other hand, in high-income States’ share in revenue from irrigation projects increased from 7.2 percent to 11.9 percent of economic services and from 2.8 percent to 4.6 percent of States’ Ontr for the period under consideration (Table 2.9). Over the years, the average contribution by major, medium and minor irrigation in high-income States, as percent to economic services, has been 7.5 percent and 0.6 percent respectively. In middle-income States the share of major and medium irrigation’s was 3.7 percent, while 0.9 was of minor irrigation’s contribution. For low-income States 6.3 percent was contributed by major and medium irrigation while minor irrigation contributed about 1.7 percent. However, these figures are almost reversed in case of revenue from irrigation as percent of States’ Ontr, where the average share in low-income States was highest (4.1 percent) followed by high-income States (2.4 percent) and middle-income States (1.7 percent) (Table 2.9). The respective contribution of major and medium irrigation, and minor irrigation to Sontr and to economic services, across the States, is given in Tables 2.10 and 2.11. Over time, when all the States are taken into consideration, receipts by way of revenue from irrigation show wide variations. Goa, Kerala, Tamil Nadu, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh and Orissa contribute less than 4 percent of economic services while the States like Gujarat, Bihar, Rajasthan and Uttar Pradesh contribute more than 10 percent to economic services and rest fall in the range of 4 to 10 percent. Amidst all the 15 major States, Uttar Pradesh’s average share of revenue from irrigation in economic services is the highest, i.e. about 23 percent – (18 percent was revenue from major and medium irrigation, and 5.0 percent from minor irrigation). Goa’s contribution was least (about 0.8 percent). However, in Goa its contribution has increased with highest rate of growth (36.2 percent per annum) and showed a buoyancy of 1.9 during the period. Bihar has been the least consistent State. In spite of there being an upward trend, there were wide fluctuations in its revenue from irrigation over the years. Its share was only 2.3 percent of revenue from economic services in 1993-94, which increased to whooping 46.5 percent by 1997-98 only to decline to 4.7 percent in 1999-00. Thereafter, it increased again to 26.2 percent in 2001-02 but settled at 18.2 percent in the year 2003-04. Industries Revenue from industries constitutes an essential and major part of economic services. It comprises about 40 percent of revenue from economic services. It includes revenue from industries (under departmental undertakings), non-ferrous mining and metallurgical industries, 29 and other industries. However, out of these, revenue from minerals and mining constitute the major source of revenue from industries, as the bulk of non-tax revenue from industries is from mining in several States. It constitutes the bedrock of industrial development as these activities provide the basic raw materials for most of the industries. India produces as many as 84 minerals - 4 fuels, 11 metallic, 49 non-metallic industrial and 20 minor minerals. The distribution of the value of mineral production shows that fuel minerals accounted for about 82 percent (of which solid fuels yield 44 percent and liquid/gaseous fuels 38 percent), metallic minerals about 8 percent, non-metallic minerals 4 percent and the balance 6 percent is contributed by minor minerals. The 9,244 mining leases are spread over 21 States on about 13,000 mineral deposits buried in 0.7 million hectares, i.e. 0.21 percent of the total land mass of the country. However, different States are rich in different minerals. The legal framework for mines and minerals are given in the Mines and Minerals Regulation and Development (MMRD) Act, 1957. In particular, this Act distinguishes between major and minor minerals, classified as per the decision of the Parliament. However, the States get receipts from these minerals. The Centre has royalty rate setting powers for the former, while States have it for the latter. Revenue generation from industries as a percent of revenue from economic services shows an upward trend. However, the average ratio varies widely across States from as low as 1.3 percent in case of Punjab to as high as 74.2 percent in case of Rajasthan over the years (Table 2.12). Ten out of 15 major States have exhibited a rising trend in revenue from industries. In 1993-94, the share of revenue from industries as a percent of economic services was highest in Bihar (84.5 percent) followed by Gujarat (80.4 percent), Rajasthan (72.7 percent), and Andhra Pradesh (52.9 percent); Orissa took over the lead position in the year 2003-04 contributing about 82.2 percent followed by Rajasthan (78 percent) and Gujarat (72.8 percent) (Table 2.12). Amongst 15 major States, the average contribution of 5 States was less than 20 percent to economic services while in other 6 States it contributed more than 50 percent. The average share of revenue from industries in economic services is highest in lowincome States (57.5 percent). The share of middle-income States was 34.8 percent and that of the high-income States 29.1 percent. In terms of growth rate, in low-income States it was the least (less than 1 percent), while the middle-income and high-income States had a growth rate of 12.6 percent and 11.7 percent, respectively. Amongst these categories, while the middleincome States are the most invariant States; low-income States are the most consistent. As a percent to States Ontr, revenue from industries has been highest in low-income States. These States contributed on an average about 30.1 percent per annum while middle-income States and high-income States contributed 12.5 percent and 8.7 percent, respectively (Table 2.12). Further, in almost all States share of revenue from mining and minerals is more than 95 percent of revenue from industries. The mining and minerals industry contributes to the Centre and State Government revenue through payments of royalty, dead rent, cess, sales tax, excise 30 duties and custom duties. It may be observed that the average percentage increase in revenue from mining and metallurgical is highest in case of middle-income States (156.5 percent). This was 142.7 percent in high-income States, whereas the low-income States saw a decline of -10.7 percent in their average percentage share. Across the States, the highest percentage increase was in Haryana, Punjab, Kerala and Tamil Nadu while the States of West Bengal, Bihar and Madhya Pradesh exhibited a decline. Looking at the components of the non-ferrous and metallurgical industries, the rise in average percentage share in mineral concession fees and royalties is highest in the State of Orissa (526.7 percent). This was 368.4 percent in Punjab & 348.9 percent in Karnataka. Three States of West Bengal, Bihar and Uttar Pradesh showed a decline in their average percentage share. In case of other receipts, 5 out of 15 major States exhibited decline in their average percentage share, while there was an increase in the rest of the States. The increase was highest in Kerala followed by Goa and West Bengal. However, the average percentage change in revenue from carbide of calcium rules and mines department cannot be calculated because of their negligible share over the year. Summing-up The foregoing analysis of the fiscal significance of States Ontr clearly reveals that own non-tax sources are not fiscally significant in the overall fiscal map of the States vis-à-vis other State level aggregates, namely, States’ own tax revenue etc. These are neither growing to keep pace with other components of resources nor showing any significant buoyancy. Their receipts are dependent on various policy decisions, which are less economic and more political. Basically, on economic fronts, the cost recovery policies are somewhere falling too short of expectations. They are, in turn, dependent on how the pricing policies are determined. Every service needs its own tailored mechanism, keeping in views the social welfare objective of the Government. It is not out of place to emphasize that potentials are there but the dire need is to take a firm decision and to implement them firmly. A viable cost recovery may turn the poor quality of service delivery into reliable and dependable one. 31 Table 2.1 Non-tax Revenue in Different Countries Name of Country Albania Algeria Argentina Australia Austria Azerbaijan Belarus Belgium Bolivia Botswana Brazil Bulgaria Burkina Faso Burundi Cameroon Canada Chad Chile China Colombia Congo, Dem. Rep. Congo, Rep. Costa Rica Cote d'lvoire Croatia Czech Republic Denmark Dominican Republic Ecuador Egypt, Arab Rep. Estonia Ethiopia Finland France Georgia Germany Ghana Greece Guatemala Guinea Hungary India Current Non-tax Revenue (Percentage of GDP) 1990 1998 0 4.5 0 1.5 1 1.2 2.1 1.6 3 2.5 0 1.1 0.5 2.1 1.5 0.7 5.2 2.4 23.4 29.5 3.7 0 12.6 6.9 0.8 0 1.9 1 4.3 0 2.7 0 0.5 0 4.3 3.6 2.4 0.2 2.1 1.4 0.7 1 7.8 22.8 3.3 3.2 2.1 0.6 1.1 2.1 0 1.1 5.5 0 1.2 1.4 0.4 0 6.2 9.7 0.6 1.8 5.1 0 2.8 3.9 2.8 2.6 0 1 1.4 5.1 1 0 2.3 2.4 0 0 4.6 0.4 8.2 4.2 2.4 3 Non-tax Revenue as Percentage of Total Revenue 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 23.38 10.02 9.46 6.33 5.94 5.44 6.51 1.62 19.11 16.29 23.4 6.46 8.58 17.91 5.96 14.36 7.84 77.43 9.72 4.88 4.28 11.79 7.78 9.03 29.43 13.16 15.94 6.98 9.48 3.9 10.68 22.69 32 Name of Country Indonesia Iran, Islamic, Rep. Ireland Israel Italy Jordan Kazakhstan Kenya Korea, Rep. Kuwait Kyrgyz Republic Latvia Lebanon Lesotho Lithuania Macedonia, FYR Madagascar Malawi Malaysia Mexico Moldova Mongolia Morocco Myanmar Namibia Nepal Netherlands New Zealand Nicaragua Norway Pakistan Panama Papua New Guinea Paraguay Peru Philippines Poland Portugal Romania Russian Federation Senegal Sierra Leone Singapore Slovak Republic Slovenia South Africa Spain Current Non-tax Revenue (Percentage of GDP) 1 1.2 10.8 15.3 2.4 1.6 5.7 6.4 1.2 2.9 7.5 6.7 0 0 2.2 3.7 1.7 2.7 0 0 0 0 0 3.8 0 4.3 4.3 9.8 2.6 1.3 0 0 2.1 0.2 2.7 0 7.5 4.1 1.6 1.7 0 0 2.7 6 3.5 0 4.3 3.3 4 0 1.4 1.8 4.2 3 6.2 2.1 4.3 0 10.2 9.1 5.8 3.3 7.9 7 5.2 0 3.1 0 0.6 2.3 2.1 2 0 2.9 4 3.6 3.5 2.1 0 0 0 0 0.2 0.3 11.5 8.4 0 0 0 0 2 1.7 1.6 2 Non-tax Revenue as Percentage of Total Revenue 36.09 58.65 6.89 12.2 24.24 14.88 17.76 90.01 17.04 7.01 27.97 21.9 8.78 3.12 10.46 10.41 24.69 15.5 43.43 8.37 16.36 6.15 8.69 19.59 8.52 37.33 3.73 41.02 13.82 12.59 11.47 9.7 14.48 16.25 4.3 33.75 11.08 6.29 4.97 33 Current Non-tax Revenue Non-tax Revenue as Percentage of Name of Country (Percentage of GDP) Total Revenue Sri Lanka 2 2.7 11.53 Sweden 5.8 4.5 11.29 Switzerland 1.4 1.7 7.05 Syrian Arab Republic 5.1 7.8 27.2 Tajikistan 0 0 8.76 Thailand 1.5 1.8 17.5 Tunisia 6.7 4.8 8.85 Turkey 2.1 2.8 16.14 Uganda 0 0 0.97 Ukraine 0 0 28.18 United Kingdom 3.2 2 4.89 United States 1.5 1.4 6.37 Uruguay 1.3 2.3 7.25 Venezuela, RB 5.3 4.6 42.23 Vietnam 0 2.4 15.92 Yemen, Rep. 8.3 23.1 60.3 Zambia 0 0 3.63 Zimbabwe 2.4 3 Source: International Monetary Fund. 2006. Government Finance Statistics, June. Washington D C. 34 Table 2.2 All-States Own Non-Tax Revenue and its Composition Rs. in Crores Particulars States’ Own Non-Tax Revenue 1993-94 2003-04 As % of AR 1993-94 As % of CR 2003-04 1993-94 As % of NTR 2003-04 1993-94 2003-04 As percent of GDP 1993-94 2003-04 As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 As % of SOR 1993-94 2003-04 G* B* 15568.83 38188.57 11.60 2.87 14.75 12.06 42.37 42.65 1.99 1.52 100 100 25.11 19.28 7.85 0.66 4725.44 8616.59 3.52 0.65 4.48 2.72 12.86 9.62 0.60 0.34 30.35 22.56 7.62 4.35 7.07 0.62 62.03 390.68 0.05 0.03 0.06 0.12 0.17 0.44 0.01 0.02 0.40 1.02 0.10 0.20 16.37 1.31 (iii) General services 2947.23 9372.43 2.20 0.70 2.79 2.96 8.02 10.47 0.38 0.37 18.93 24.54 4.75 4.73 6.44 0.54 (iv) Social Services 912.41 3282.92 0.68 0.25 0.86 1.04 2.48 3.67 0.12 0.13 5.86 8.60 1.47 1.66 14.48 1.18 6921.13 16525.45 5.16 1.24 6.56 5.22 18.84 18.46 0.89 0.66 44.46 43.27 11.16 8.34 8.39 0.69 (i) Interest Receipts (ii) Dividends and Profits (v) Economic Services Notes: Abbreviations AR = Aggregate Receipts, CR = Current Receipts, NTR = Non-Tax Revenue, GDP = Gross Domestic Product, SONTR = States’ Own Non-Tax Revenue, SOR = States Own Revenue, GDSP = Gross State Domestic Product. Avg. in a table is the average of the head for the period 1993-94 to 2003-04. G* in a table is the Growth Rate of that Particular Head for the period 1993-94 to 2003-04. B* in a table is the buoyancy of the particular head w.r.t. GSDP for the period 1993-94 to 2003-04. @ In Table 2.7 Growth Rate and Buoyancy has been calculated for the period 1995-96 to 2003-04 due to the lack of availability of data. Also, the average has been taken for the same period. Source: RBI, “State Finances: A Study of Budgets”, Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai, (Table 2.2 to Table 2.12). 35 Table 2.3 State-wise Own Non-Tax Revenue and its Composition States 1993-94 SONTR as percent of GSDP 2003-04 Avg. G* As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. B* General Services As % of GSDP 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. G* B* High Income States 2.61 2.17 2.79 7.89 0.73 21.46 31.56 31.20 0.56 0.68 0.89 7.29 0.69 1. Goa 5.68 7.50 9.72 21.01 1.35 2.84 1.25 35.75 0.16 0.09 3.97 27.53 2.05 2. Gujarat 2.84 1.96 2.54 12.08 1.01 3.81 9.11 9.61 0.11 0.18 0.25 24.06 1.99 3. Haryana 6.06 3.01 5.40 -2.86 -0.23 64.36 30.51 51.11 3.90 0.92 3.30 -12.56 -1.10 4. Maharashtra 2.10 1.07 1.82 5.79 0.55 9.66 27.52 12.07 0.20 0.29 0.20 15.48 1.36 5. Punjab 1.37 5.75 4.32 17.00 1.58 16.31 55.58 55.93 0.22 3.20 2.54 27.34 2.43 Middle Income States 1.45 1.32 1.27 10.29 0.84 10.04 28.65 14.79 0.15 0.38 0.19 18.26 1.42 6. Andhra Pradesh 2.34 1.95 1.98 10.92 0.90 3.91 7.61 5.51 0.09 0.15 0.11 13.88 1.15 7. Karnataka 1.79 2.23 1.71 8.44 0.72 9.47 60.30 16.53 0.17 1.35 0.29 24.16 1.73 8. Kerala 1.23 0.90 1.04 6.79 0.58 27.55 38.05 33.92 0.34 0.34 0.34 11.74 0.96 9. Tamil Nadu 1.22 1.24 1.12 11.79 1.03 10.43 16.29 16.25 0.13 0.20 0.18 18.39 1.59 10. West Bengal 0.58 0.32 0.49 10.48 0.79 18.97 29.54 25.49 0.11 0.09 0.12 12.15 0.94 Low Income States 2.91 1.39 2.03 1.01 0.12 22.60 14.35 17.37 0.66 0.20 0.39 -5.00 -0.63 11. Bihar 3.89 0.79 2.43 -8.43 -0.79 2.65 27.09 14.95 0.10 0.21 0.21 22.22 2.24 12. Madhya Pradesh 3.70 1.46 2.87 -0.06 0.07 5.98 8.49 8.38 0.22 0.12 0.22 8.81 0.88 13. Orissa 2.24 2.03 1.99 7.33 0.73 9.99 5.13 9.19 0.22 0.10 0.18 2.75 0.33 14. Rajasthan 3.58 1.98 2.50 2.71 0.24 22.23 22.73 22.83 0.80 0.45 0.68 -5.64 -0.59 15. Uttar Pradesh 2.13 1.06 1.34 1.66 0.10 49.79 12.46 26.29 1.06 0.13 0.43 -11.33 -1.46 All Non-Special States 1.61 1.26 1.45 7.53 0.68 19.27 24.70 23.21 0.31 0.31 0.34 5.85 0.52 All States 1.99 1.52 1.79 7.85 0.66 18.93 24.54 24.59 0.38 0.37 0.45 6.44 0.54 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.2 36 Table 2.3 Contd…. States As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. Social Services As % of GSDP 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. G* B* As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. Economic Services As % of GSDP 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. G* B* High Income States 5.60 7.10 5.30 0.15 0.15 0.14 13.96 1.23 38.94 38.80 29.94 1.02 0.84 0.80 9.26 0.82 1. Goa 9.51 10.47 7.02 0.54 0.79 0.64 21.27 1.32 85.39 87.97 56.38 4.85 6.60 5.05 19.8 1.21 2. Gujarat 5.00 5.96 5.19 0.14 0.12 0.13 16.76 1.30 34.04 56.59 33.38 0.97 1.11 0.82 14 1.16 3. Haryana 3.00 11.98 6.58 0.18 0.36 0.25 18.86 1.47 23.88 35.82 28.02 1.45 1.08 1.13 9.41 0.76 4. Maharashtra 6.25 10.76 6.79 0.13 0.11 0.12 10.77 1.00 45.01 51.13 39.00 0.95 0.54 0.68 5.32 0.49 11.02 2.27 3.34 0.15 0.13 0.12 9.32 0.86 54.04 10.73 15.95 0.74 0.62 0.54 5.37 0.50 Middle Income States 9.14 10.64 9.80 0.13 0.14 0.12 13.97 1.12 38.66 33.71 36.15 0.56 0.44 0.45 9.66 0.78 6. Andhra Pradesh 5.25 6.91 6.13 0.12 0.14 0.12 19.86 1.57 38.61 33.67 35.88 0.90 0.66 0.70 8.38 0.68 7. Karnataka 7.23 4.17 8.68 0.13 0.09 0.14 9.67 0.82 36.64 31.20 37.65 0.65 0.70 0.61 12.2 0.99 8. Kerala 12.96 15.82 12.65 0.16 0.14 0.13 10.38 0.81 49.73 39.64 43.17 0.61 0.36 0.44 3.97 0.35 9. Tamil Nadu 12.46 22.77 15.13 0.15 0.28 0.17 15.77 1.35 35.95 34.21 33.05 0.44 0.43 0.37 12 1.03 10. West Bengal 19.15 15.62 13.93 0.11 0.05 0.07 8.18 0.62 38.23 36.59 37.45 0.22 0.12 0.17 10.2 0.75 Low Income States 4.52 11.95 8.31 0.13 0.17 0.15 13.55 1.33 49.46 50.46 52.19 1.44 0.70 1.01 1.21 0.17 11. Bihar 3.55 28.06 10.51 0.14 0.22 0.15 11.79 1.14 90.10 38.12 62.76 3.50 0.30 1.66 -16.3 -1.68 12. Madhya Pradesh 3.67 5.49 3.95 0.14 0.08 0.11 6.56 0.70 74.91 84.15 77.61 2.77 1.23 2.18 -0.26 0.05 13. Orissa 6.76 5.90 7.23 0.15 0.12 0.14 11.63 1.09 62.00 61.33 70.44 1.39 1.25 1.40 6.6 0.67 14. Rajasthan 6.63 12.21 10.02 0.24 0.24 0.23 10.99 0.97 19.11 31.86 27.62 0.68 0.63 0.63 10.6 0.94 15. Uttar Pradesh 3.74 15.66 12.08 0.08 0.17 0.14 19.73 1.94 25.52 42.69 33.99 0.54 0.45 0.41 8.24 0.81 All Non-Special States 6.02 8.76 6.97 0.10 0.11 0.10 14.18 1.24 42.85 41.55 37.98 0.69 0.52 0.54 7.95 0.70 All States 5.86 8.60 6.70 0.12 0.13 0.12 14.48 1.18 44.46 43.27 38.72 0.89 0.66 0.67 8.39 0.69 5. Punjab 37 Table 2.4 The Role of Education etc. in Social Services, SONTR and GSDP States High Income States 1. Goa 2. Gujarat 3. Haryana 4. Maharashtra 5. Punjab Middle Income States 6. Andhra Pradesh 7. Karnataka 8. Kerala 9. Tamil Nadu 10. West Bengal Low Income States 11. Bihar 12. Madhya Pradesh 13. Orissa 14. Rajasthan 15. Uttar Pradesh All Non-Special States All States As % of Social Services 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 18.73 19.05 17.15 2.94 15.16 4.94 25.87 32.64 25.17 30.01 12.26 19.57 15.60 17.32 14.78 12.51 20.10 16.46 31.56 30.51 32.12 42.32 28.57 44.38 33.32 24.40 21.80 51.96 64.13 56.85 28.29 25.71 25.49 7.45 22.41 16.86 21.14 43.80 30.90 16.75 46.70 22.64 9.73 11.18 16.00 33.92 18.57 31.70 4.94 31.15 11.40 46.57 63.70 51.94 24.01 30.07 26.46 24.04 31.47 26.53 As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 1.05 1.35 0.89 0.28 1.59 0.37 1.29 1.95 1.27 0.90 1.47 1.08 0.97 1.86 0.99 1.38 0.46 0.52 2.89 3.25 3.19 2.22 1.98 2.99 2.41 1.02 1.82 6.73 10.14 7.26 3.53 5.85 3.82 1.43 3.50 2.27 0.96 5.23 2.74 0.59 13.10 3.29 0.36 0.61 0.62 2.29 1.10 2.28 0.33 3.80 1.22 1.74 9.98 6.49 1.45 2.63 1.87 1.41 2.71 1.80 As % of GSDP 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.12 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.03 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.04 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.08 0.09 0.07 0.04 0.07 0.04 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.07 0.05 0.02 0.10 0.04 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.04 0.01 0.08 0.03 0.04 0.11 0.07 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.03 G* 11.29 30.19 15.47 9.64 7.48 12.18 16.71 21.48 10.74 12.56 15.84 18.21 20.58 12.19 7.31 7.42 22.55 23.51 16.82 17.49 B* 1.01 1.72 1.28 0.78 0.69 1.14 1.30 1.71 0.82 0.96 1.28 1.28 1.94 1.25 0.91 0.67 1.86 2.22 1.44 1.38 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.2 Table 2.5 The Role of Medical and Public Health in Social Services, SONTR and GSDP States High Income States 1. Goa 2. Gujarat 3. Haryana 4. Maharashtra 5. Punjab Middle Income States 6. Andhra Pradesh 7. Karnataka 8. Kerala 9. Tamil Nadu 10. West Bengal Low Income States 11. Bihar 12. Madhya Pradesh 13. Orissa 14. Rajasthan 15. Uttar Pradesh All Non-Special States All States As % of Social Services 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 39.53 22.36 29.08 11.59 9.62 10.11 46.33 21.95 32.74 31.08 12.06 18.69 39.04 27.61 32.78 46.10 39.23 38.77 40.91 19.10 30.01 27.28 11.85 20.66 42.82 36.75 31.28 72.81 22.47 33.81 18.94 18.88 19.65 24.75 35.10 34.90 26.82 21.68 13.92 50.73 11.18 15.37 14.97 11.68 6.48 12.08 18.01 17.70 30.34 29.17 27.70 59.37 16.00 30.03 18.56 16.23 10.98 16.09 25.31 25.08 As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 2.21 1.59 1.50 1.10 1.01 0.71 2.32 1.31 1.60 0.93 1.44 1.13 2.44 2.97 2.19 5.08 0.89 1.35 3.74 2.03 2.91 1.43 0.82 1.13 3.10 4.76 3.90 13.94 1.02 1.20 0.69 1.28 1.30 0.93 2.11 2.05 1.12 3.43 3.17 7.92 1.34 4.31 0.82 0.69 0.79 1.89 1.58 1.52 2.64 3.65 4.09 8.28 1.27 2.75 0.73 1.18 1.05 1.76 1.72 1.64 As % of GSDP 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 0.06 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.06 0.07 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.03 0.04 0.07 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.06 0.06 0.05 0.08 0.03 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.04 0.02 0.04 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.03 G* B* 7.85 17.68 5.19 13.24 6.85 9.82 8.88 10.93 0.70 1.11 0.42 1.05 0.64 0.88 0.73 0.89 8.75 6.58 12.22 5.24 8.57 9.90 5.60 9.18 4.92 11.32 8.82 9.05 0.70 0.53 1.10 0.40 0.85 0.97 0.57 0.85 0.36 1.18 0.78 0.74 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.2 38 Table 2.6 The Role of Urban Development in Social Services and SONTR States High Income States 1. Goa 2. Gujarat 3. Haryana 4. Maharashtra 5. Punjab Middle Income States 6. Andhra Pradesh 7. Karnataka 8. Kerala 9. Tamil Nadu 10. West Bengal Low Income States 11. Bihar 12. Madhya Pradesh 13. Orissa 14. Rajasthan 15. Uttar Pradesh All Non-Special States All States As % of Social Services 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 6.60 21.32 11.85 0.00 0.03 0.02 6.85 11.56 6.03 7.71 53.90 31.47 8.31 13.21 9.03 1.53 1.89 2.72 1.30 19.01 6.25 1.65 1.79 2.82 0.57 1.87 12.24 4.23 1.30 3.45 0.68 40.83 4.11 0.41 0.66 0.96 1.15 1.63 1.17 0.70 0.01 0.81 4.10 1.51 1.80 1.07 0.03 0.33 0.29 0.38 0.27 0.08 3.40 1.68 3.16 14.25 6.61 3.07 13.46 6.36 As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 0.37 1.51 0.65 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.34 0.69 0.31 0.23 6.46 2.53 0.52 1.42 0.62 0.17 0.04 0.08 0.12 2.02 0.59 0.09 0.12 0.15 0.04 0.08 1.12 0.55 0.21 0.40 0.09 9.30 0.90 0.08 0.10 0.14 0.05 0.19 0.11 0.02 0.00 0.05 0.15 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.00 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.03 0.00 0.53 0.27 0.19 1.25 0.47 0.18 1.16 0.44 G* B* 22.78 0.00 20.19 39.61 9.61 8.00 11.09 13.11 2.02 -12.00 37.18 12.26 23.90 -8.16 2.54 -12.00 0.00 79.03 20.35 20.47 2.03 0.00 1.64 2.88 1.00 0.80 0.87 1.07 0.48 -0.98 2.48 1.02 1.98 -1.10 0.13 -1.48 0.00 5.54 1.82 1.67 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.12 Table 2.7 The Role of Water Supply and Sanitation in Social Services and SONTR@ States High Income States 1. Goa 2. Gujarat 3. Haryana 4. Maharashtra 5. Punjab Middle Income States 6. Andhra Pradesh 7. Karnataka 8. Kerala 9. Tamil Nadu 10. West Bengal Low Income States 11. Bihar 12. Madhya Pradesh 13. Orissa 14. Rajasthan 15. Uttar Pradesh All Non-Special States All States As % of Social Services 1995-96 2003-04 Avg. 10.02 12.70 9.80 80.73 72.01 67.40 0.91 0.52 0.56 24.95 14.01 15.97 2.10 2.73 1.96 4.65 25.30 14.28 2.82 2.11 2.17 8.36 2.48 4.20 1.56 0.49 1.00 0.41 2.15 1.19 2.07 1.42 2.07 3.19 6.66 2.42 28.78 21.95 20.18 4.57 0.35 2.59 20.46 24.18 13.60 21.53 37.39 23.34 65.08 57.83 57.04 0.08 0.81 0.24 13.03 11.65 10.35 13.34 12.29 10.61 As % of SONTR 1995-96 2003-04 Avg. 0.39 0.90 0.54 3.86 7.54 4.36 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.60 1.68 1.15 0.12 0.29 0.14 0.10 0.57 0.37 0.24 0.22 0.22 0.32 0.17 0.24 0.13 0.02 0.09 0.05 0.34 0.16 0.28 0.32 0.32 0.46 1.04 0.32 1.17 2.62 1.81 0.15 0.10 0.20 0.53 1.33 0.57 1.02 2.21 1.76 3.36 7.06 6.08 0.00 0.13 0.03 0.65 1.02 0.76 0.64 1.06 0.74 G* B* 16.53 19.32 -0.56 12.94 1.14 29.43 14.74 12.54 -7.40 32.06 15.96 25.16 10.07 2.03 10.84 16.45 9.24 NC 12.74 13.53 1.67 1.34 0.16 1.11 0.29 2.88 1.26 1.13 -0.63 2.72 1.52 1.81 1.15 0.38 1.10 1.74 1.03 NC 1.27 1.24 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.2 39 Table 2.8 The Role of Forestry and Wildlife in Economic Services, SONTR and GSDP States High Income States 1. Goa 2. Gujarat 3. Haryana 4. Maharashtra 5. Punjab Middle Income States 6. Andhra Pradesh 7. Karnataka 8. Kerala 9. Tamil Nadu 10. West Bengal Low Income States 11. Bihar 12. Madhya Pradesh 13. Orissa 14. Rajasthan 15. Uttar Pradesh All Non-Special States All States As % of Economic Services 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 7.68 3.06 6.04 0.99 0.28 0.54 3.20 2.69 2.71 3.70 3.20 4.17 12.68 4.76 9.95 2.36 1.61 3.14 26.70 17.59 22.73 13.50 7.66 13.02 34.22 19.57 23.45 64.05 58.52 59.40 21.84 12.59 20.45 27.50 20.74 20.73 30.23 19.29 23.01 8.76 12.36 6.09 46.80 39.89 35.58 38.62 7.25 19.58 24.48 13.67 20.14 27.64 6.26 17.97 21.58 11.18 16.31 21.58 11.67 16.50 As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 2.99 1.19 1.77 0.84 0.25 0.33 1.09 1.52 0.91 0.88 1.15 1.15 5.71 2.43 3.87 1.28 0.17 0.45 10.32 5.93 8.23 5.21 2.58 4.75 12.54 6.11 8.43 31.85 23.20 25.84 7.85 4.31 6.78 10.51 7.59 7.85 14.95 9.73 11.95 7.89 4.71 3.74 35.06 33.57 27.73 23.94 4.44 13.78 4.68 4.35 5.54 7.05 2.67 5.80 9.25 4.64 6.17 9.59 5.05 6.37 As % of GSDP 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 0.08 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.05 0.03 0.05 0.12 0.03 0.07 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.15 0.08 0.11 0.12 0.05 0.09 0.22 0.14 0.14 0.39 0.21 0.28 0.10 0.05 0.08 0.06 0.02 0.04 0.43 0.14 0.25 0.31 0.04 0.10 1.30 0.49 0.81 0.54 0.09 0.28 0.17 0.09 0.13 0.15 0.03 0.08 0.15 0.06 0.09 0.19 0.08 0.12 G* B* -0.48 -1.53 10.51 8.14 -4.61 10.83 2.29 -3.93 2.96 1.61 9.98 -0.58 -2.19 0.00 -3.16 -2.82 9.98 -4.15 0.49 1.50 -0.04 -0.17 0.89 0.68 -0.45 1.04 0.19 -0.32 0.24 0.15 0.86 -0.12 -0.23 0.00 -0.37 -0.35 0.77 -0.35 0.04 0.12 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.2 Table 2.9 The Role of Irrigation Projects in Economic Services and SONTR As % of Economic Services States 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. G* B* High Income States 1. Goa 2. Gujarat 7.24 11.88 8.01 2.82 4.61 2.44 13.42 1.15 0.29 6.96 0.75 11.54 0.81 12.48 0.25 2.37 0.66 6.53 0.45 4.06 36.23 22.84 1.85 1.88 3. Haryana 6.38 23.00 9.13 1.52 8.24 2.82 20.16 1.53 4. Maharashtra 8.33 13.85 6.59 3.75 7.08 2.69 6.19 0.50 5. Punjab 7.41 2.51 7.53 4.00 0.27 1.21 -5.39 -0.57 Middle Income States 6. Andhra Pradesh 7. Karnataka 8.86 2.37 4.56 3.43 0.80 1.68 -7.58 -0.74 16.73 5.30 1.40 1.74 6.30 4.03 6.46 1.94 0.47 0.54 2.49 1.50 -22.42 3.55 -2.30 0.32 1.77 2.34 1.90 0.88 0.93 0.81 7.94 0.67 8. Kerala 9. Tamil Nadu 2.32 2.75 2.58 0.83 0.94 0.84 11.71 1.03 10. West Bengal 5.92 9.15 5.45 2.26 3.35 2.02 7.36 0.54 Low Income States 11. Bihar 12. Madhya Pradesh 9.78 8.82 7.96 4.84 4.45 4.12 2.26 0.21 2.27 3.06 18.16 3.62 12.24 3.26 2.05 2.30 6.92 3.04 4.88 2.52 2.53 0.37 0.31 0.12 13. Orissa 2.47 5.37 3.05 1.53 3.30 2.10 17.16 1.62 14. Rajasthan 13.89 9.31 11.10 2.65 2.97 2.91 4.21 0.40 15. Uttar Pradesh 41.78 15.87 22.99 10.66 6.78 7.50 0.79 -0.03 All Non-Special States 8.70 7.90 7.00 3.73 3.28 2.67 6.58 0.55 All States 7.95 7.06 6.40 3.53 3.06 2.48 6.76 0.52 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.2 40 Table 2.10 The Role of Major and Medium Irrigation in Economic Services and SONTR States High Income States 1. Goa 2. Gujarat 3. Haryana 4. Maharashtra 5. Punjab Middle Income States 6. Andhra Pradesh 7. Karnataka 8. Kerala 9. Tamil Nadu 10. West Bengal Low Income States 11. Bihar 12. Madhya Pradesh 13. Orissa 14. Rajasthan 15. Uttar Pradesh All Non-Special States All States As % of Economic Services 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 6.62 11.28 7.46 0.15 0.46 0.54 6.51 10.95 12.02 6.37 22.98 9.05 7.30 12.71 5.77 7.33 2.49 7.10 7.46 1.48 3.70 14.72 1.28 5.62 5.04 1.28 3.59 1.47 1.91 1.58 1.45 1.77 1.79 1.96 1.80 1.71 8.11 7.51 6.25 1.88 17.66 11.41 2.21 3.04 2.59 2.14 4.81 2.64 8.82 6.55 6.54 36.78 13.97 17.96 7.45 7.06 5.94 6.81 6.30 5.42 As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 2.58 4.38 2.28 0.13 0.41 0.28 2.22 6.20 3.90 1.52 8.23 2.81 3.29 6.50 2.36 3.96 0.27 1.16 2.88 0.50 1.37 5.68 0.43 2.23 1.85 0.40 1.33 0.73 0.76 0.67 0.52 0.61 0.58 0.75 0.66 0.63 4.01 3.79 3.23 1.69 6.73 4.52 1.66 2.55 2.01 1.32 2.95 1.81 1.69 2.09 1.72 9.39 5.96 5.91 3.19 2.93 2.27 3.03 2.73 2.11 G* B* 14.37 31.73 23.61 20.44 7.46 -4.83 -9.96 -22.89 1.70 8.10 14.47 4.68 3.09 2.57 -0.13 18.20 4.34 2.57 7.52 7.70 1.23 1.62 1.93 1.55 0.61 -0.53 -0.96 -2.37 0.17 0.69 1.29 0.35 0.27 0.31 0.09 1.68 0.44 0.06 0.62 0.59 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.2 Table 2.11 The Role of Minor Irrigation in Economic Services and SONTR States High Income States 1. Goa 2. Gujarat 3. Haryana 4. Maharashtra 5. Punjab Middle Income States 6. Andhra Pradesh 7. Karnataka 8. Kerala 9. Tamil Nadu 10. West Bengal Low Income States 11. Bihar 12. Madhya Pradesh 13. Orissa 14. Rajasthan 15. Uttar Pradesh All Non-Special States All States As % of Economic Services 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 0.62 0.60 0.55 0.14 0.28 0.27 0.45 0.59 0.46 0.02 0.02 0.08 1.03 1.14 0.82 0.07 0.03 0.43 1.40 0.89 0.86 2.01 0.12 0.68 0.26 0.46 0.44 0.30 0.43 0.32 0.87 0.97 0.79 3.96 7.34 3.74 1.67 1.31 1.71 0.39 0.50 0.83 0.85 0.58 0.67 0.33 0.56 0.41 5.07 2.76 4.56 5.00 1.90 5.03 1.24 0.85 1.06 1.14 0.76 0.97 As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 0.24 0.23 0.16 0.12 0.25 0.16 0.15 0.33 0.16 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.46 0.58 0.33 0.04 0.00 0.05 0.54 0.30 0.31 0.78 0.04 0.26 0.10 0.14 0.17 0.15 0.17 0.14 0.31 0.33 0.26 1.51 2.69 1.38 0.83 0.66 0.89 0.36 0.19 0.37 0.64 0.49 0.51 0.21 0.35 0.29 0.97 0.88 1.19 1.28 0.81 1.59 0.53 0.35 0.40 0.51 0.33 0.37 G* B* 0.66 32.17 7.34 -0.74 -3.60 -8.30 1.50 -19.31 18.34 7.77 6.25 8.34 -1.06 2.46 1.91 9.73 3.05 -6.95 1.03 1.21 0.08 1.69 0.73 0.08 -0.39 -0.76 0.08 -1.89 1.47 0.61 0.50 0.61 -0.05 0.34 0.20 1.11 0.24 -0.58 0.11 0.11 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.2 41 Table 2.12 The Role of Industries in Economic Services and SONTR States High Income States 1. Goa 2. Gujarat 3. Haryana 4. Maharashtra 5. Punjab Middle Income States 6. Andhra Pradesh 7. Karnataka 8. Kerala 9. Tamil Nadu 10. West Bengal Low Income States 11. Bihar 12. Madhya Pradesh 13. Orissa 14. Rajasthan 15. Uttar Pradesh All Non-Special States All States As % of Economic Services 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 25.11 34.62 29.06 7.99 3.05 4.97 80.44 72.84 73.90 5.84 9.70 12.53 13.29 26.59 20.72 0.46 2.17 1.32 30.55 42.09 34.76 52.85 64.50 57.81 18.71 25.13 24.87 3.15 5.78 5.75 21.74 52.73 31.95 15.15 8.04 9.79 54.60 54.89 57.45 84.48 44.28 66.76 45.61 52.13 51.19 50.94 82.24 66.92 72.70 77.95 74.24 14.52 25.78 28.28 39.21 48.11 43.50 36.25 43.67 40.43 As % of SONTR 1993-94 2003-04 Avg. 9.78 13.43 8.72 6.82 2.68 2.88 27.38 41.23 24.80 1.39 3.47 3.96 5.98 13.60 8.06 0.25 0.23 0.17 11.81 14.19 12.54 20.40 21.72 20.54 6.86 7.84 9.18 1.57 2.29 2.44 7.81 18.04 10.74 5.79 2.94 3.61 27.00 27.70 30.05 76.11 16.88 48.34 34.17 43.87 39.77 31.59 50.44 46.97 13.89 24.84 20.64 3.71 11.01 9.58 16.80 19.99 16.53 16.12 18.90 15.65 G* 11.67 7.21 12.12 21.22 9.07 22.03 12.62 11.44 11.39 12.09 19.99 -3.85 0.61 -18.67 -0.08 12.46 11.52 10.72 9.34 9.47 B* 1.02 0.46 1.02 1.66 0.86 1.98 1.00 0.93 0.93 1.02 1.68 -0.30 0.13 -1.93 0.09 1.25 1.02 1.10 0.82 0.77 Note: For meaning of abbreviations see notes at the end of Table 2.2 42 Exhibit 2.1 Components of All-States Non-tax Revenue 50.00 45.00 44.46 As percent to States Own Non-tax Revenue 43.27 40.52 40.00 37.10 35.76 40.08 38.85 36.86 38.49 36.44 35.00 34.08 33.71 33.34 30.00 26.27 25.00 22.63 20.00 24.67 24.54 7.96 24.54 22.41 20.08 18.93 19.35 15.00 8.60 10.00 5.86 5.00 4.45 4.78 5.10 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 7.45 7.35 7.92 6.90 7.33 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 0.00 1993-94 General Services Social Services 2002-03 2003-04 Economic Services Source: RBI, “State Finances: A Study of Budgets”, Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 43 Exhibit 2.2(a) Share of components of Social Services (1993-94) Other Social Services 19% Water supply and sanitation 0% Social security and welfare 8% Labour and employment 5% Education,sports,arts and culture 24% M edical,public health and family welfare 35% Urban development 3% Housing 6% Exhibit 2.2(b) Share of components of Social Services (2003-04) Other Social Services 7% Water supply and sanitation 12% Education,sports,arts and culture 32% Social security and welfare 6% Labour and employment 4% Urbal development 13% Housing 8% M edical,public health and family welfare 18% Source: RBI, “State Finances: A Study of Budgets”, Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 44 Exhibit 2.3(a) Share of components of Economic Services (1993-94) Road transport 6.21% Forestry and wild life 21.58% M ajor and medium irrigation projects 6.81% M inor irrigations 1.14% Industries 36.25% Power 3.89% Exhibit 2.3(b) Share of components of Economic Services (2003-04) Road transport 6.28% Forestry and wild life 11.67% M ajor and medium irrigation projects 6.30% M inor irrigations 0.76% Power 7.13% Industries 43.87% Source: RBI, “State Finances: A Study of Budgets”, Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 45 3 Pricing Strategy for Non-tax Sources Introduction The analysis in the previous chapter clearly highlights the fiscal significance of the States’ own non-tax sources. The trend indicates that while non-tax sources are one of the constituents of total revenue receipts, but these do not play a very significant role in financing State expenditure. The growth of receipts from own nontax sources has neither kept pace with receipts from the other revenue sources nor is it showing the requisite buoyancy needed for an efficient fiscal system. In fact, politicoeconomic considerations play a decisive role in the growth of non-tax revenue receipts. At present, the ‘user’ charges for the services provided by the Government are negligible or non-existent. Hence, it is generally believed that the user charges must be augmented to reduce the burgeoning Government subsidies. The Government provides a variety of heterogeneous services. All of them are not amenable to cost recovery. While some services could have a price recovering the cost incurred, others may be priced just to cover a part of the expenditure incurred in their provision. Also, there are few services for which consumers are not charged at all. The policy to recover expenses should depend upon the type of services provided as there cannot be any universal policy prescription for all the services provided by the Government. Keeping this in view, this chapter presents a review of literature covering pricing strategy for public utilities. The effort is to analyse the intricacies of the theoretical issues confined to services falling in different categories, viz. (i) social services- education; medical healthcare; water supply etc. and (ii) economic servicesirrigation; power; road transport etc. Thus, this analysis is confined to the pricing strategy for publicly provided private goods and public utilities only; other forms of non-tax receipts in the nature of interest, dividends etc. are not analysed 1 . Therefore, this chapter presents an analysis of the principles of user charges for recovering fully or partially the cost of provision of these services by the Government. The analysis also includes a review of various theories of utility pricing dealing with costs and problems in price measurement as well as issues involved in designing the user charges. Issues in Utility Pricing The main issue confronting utility pricing policy relates to the question as to what services should be charged and through which principle. This brings us to the issue of determination of user charges, which relates to the theory of utility pricing for goods and services provided by the Government for maximizing benefits accruing to the community. It is generally accepted that from the angle of social welfare, public goods should be financed through taxes. However, there are goods and services which are like public goods. These need to be partly subsidized. However, services having the features of private goods must be charged fully at cost price. In the initial phase of the evolution of the theory of utility pricing (in the 1930's and 1940's), the general view that prevailed was that the utility prices should be equal to marginal cost (MC), as was propounded by Clark 2 . The Government has to provide subsidy if the MC is less than average cost (AC). Hotelling 3 brought this up as an economic issue and pronounced that the market price is determined at a point of equilibrium of demand (based on marginal utility) and supply (determined by marginal cost). This view, however, did not take into account the stimulus to ‘correct’ the price if consumers were unwilling to pay the total cost. It also ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure when State enterprise superceded decisions taken by private enterprise and centralized operations superceded decentralized operations. Also, this principle involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs. It did not take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by subsidies. The theory of public goods, developed by Samuelson 4 , suggested that the goods consumed by each and every individual in the society, in the same quantity 1 It may be noted that revenue from interests and dividends are the returns from public investments in public sector enterprises whose recoveries are based on different principles. Penalties are imposed on law breaking and royalty rates are determined by the State and Central Governments depending on the nature of extracted items. 2 Clark, J.M. 1911. “Rates for Public Utilities”. American Economic Review, I, September: 473-87. 3 Hotelling, H. 1939. “The Relation of Prices to Marginal Cost in an Optimum System”. Econometrica. 7: 151-5. 4 Samuelson, Paul A. 1954. “The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure”. Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 36 (4) Nov.: 387-389. 47 with no exclusion for any individual, have the property of joint consumption or nonrivalness. In addition, a pure public good exhibits another characteristic called nonexcludability, i.e. it is not possible to exclude any individual from consuming the good irrespective of his non-payment. Such goods and services, called ‘pure’ public goods, have to be financed through taxes. Quasi-public goods, (i.e. merit goods having one of the features of pure public goods) could be subsidised or regulated by the Government through the pricing mechanism. If these goods are provided by the market, they may be under-consumed because individuals typically consider the gains or benefits at the micro/individual level; they do not consider the benefits generated at the macro level for others in society. In economic terms, consumers do not internalize the positive externalities of the consumption of the goods. Such goods, which include education, preventive healthcare etc., are important examples of producing positive externality. This is clearly demonstrated by telecommunication and transportation, especially in a federal system where each new user is linked to a network, all the users benefit as the range of potential interchange is expanded. Such merit goods are a good case for imposition of user charges but the structure of the charges must be designed keeping in view the essentiality and externalities of these goods. The provision of public goods by the Government, which is taken as negatively derived in market economies, is classified into three categories: First, given the cost differences (a higher cost of provision of goods by the Government coupled with institutional failure causing private under provision), the provision of optimal quantity of goods by the Government will be below the level that prevails when its costs are identical to that in the private sector. Secondly, where the goods relate to joint supplies and costs, (i.e. when a good is supplied to and paid for by several users), any increase in the quantity of the good supplied is equally available to all users. In this case, as proposed by Coase 5 , each user should pay according to the social incremental costs related to the individual’s demand. However, it is very difficult to clearly define incremental cost when there are joint costs. Also, given the assumptions of classical theories, this theory is at par with the theory of MC; however, the decreasing cost conditions result in different prepositions. In spite of these variations, the concept of incremental cost implies that, at the optimum investment level, the user charges should be equal to the marginal cost. This is the necessary condition for welfare maximization. The mix of goods that the 5 With perfect knowledge, zero transaction costs, no income effects, and well-specified property rights, market allocation is the same no matter which economic agent has the initial title to the property rights of the traded goods (Coase, R. H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost”. Journal of Law & Economics, 3, (1): 1-44. 48 Government should optimally provide will depend upon the extent of market imperfections and the stage of economic development. Thirdly, an acceptable rationale for Government provision of a good, even if the private sector can provide the good efficiently, is when the public provision (say through a public sector undertaking) is the least cost alternative for raising revenue needed to provide other Government goods optimally. It may be noted that though there are a few purely private or purely public goods, there exist numerous "mixed" goods that may need to be subsidized by the Government. In view of the pressure coming from various interest groups, politicians may be deterred from making decisions on cost recovery schemes in spite of these proposals for user charges being based on rational economic policy decisions. In the case of mixed goods, the first important issue is determining the proper domain of the goods to be charged. The appropriate domain is determined by the characteristics of the activities in question and the nature of the "market" for the service. The second issue relates to the proper design for such user charges. Ideally, pure "public" goods should be financed by taxes and the pure “private” goods through user charges. Mixed goods may be financed partially by user charges and partly through a combination of both, i.e. subsidy and taxes. The primary economic reason for the levy of user charges on the direct recipients of public services is to ensure optimal and efficient use of available resources. This is important when the general fund for financing is scarce. The objective is to recover costs and at the same time, to improve efficiency with which Government uses its resources. Also, it is one of the important elements of financing the increasing demand for these services in the long run. The user charges are intended to defray a part or total of the costs of a service provided and are related to the amount of services consumed. In contrast to the simple cost-recovery approach to setting fees, user charges should be approximately at the level of private sector competitive prices, with no special tax or subsidy element included. In some instances - for example, with respect to economic rent - the appropriate user charges may be determined according to "what the market will bear". This could be determined by the "mapping of demand". Sometimes the user charges could differ from the competitive level due to public policy considerations (externalities, socio-political objectives, specific characteristics of consumption or production) or problems due to insufficient information. Instances of such differences occur in publicly provided services that confer external benefits on non-users. Immunization Programme is one such case where the user charges could be less than MC. Theories of Utility Pricing 49 Based on the pricing principles and given that the Government is a natural monopoly, various models of utility pricing have been developed, keeping in mind the social welfare function 6 that maximizes conceivable, hypothetically feasible welfare measures for members of the society and the utility function 7 of consumption of real goods. Apart from equity, adopting MC principle may ensure efficiency. Also, the principle of average cost (AC) pricing ensures that there is some profit margin. The best solution would be when MC=AC. The theory of price discrimination is a combination of the two, i.e. MC and AC. The relative rationale behind these theories is important. Some of the aspects of these theories are discussed below 8 . Theory of Marginal Cost (MC) Pricing: Clark initiated the discussion in favour of MC and formulated sound intuitive theories for most of the basic issues in public utility economics. He begins with a definition of two important principles underlying pricing (rate-making) in public utilities. The first principle is of justice (or equity), i.e. each group of consumers should pay the costs without cross-subsidization. He does not consider the issue of pricing policy against the background of income distribution. 6 A social welfare function can be defined as a real-valued function that maximizes conceivable, hypothetically feasible welfare measures of members of the society given an ordering of the corresponding social States. In using individual welfare measures as input, the social welfare function is individualistic in form. Necessary general conditions of a social welfare function are that at the maximum value of the function: • The marginal "rupee’s worth" of welfare is equal for each individual and for each commodity. • The marginal "dis-welfare" of each "rupee's worth" of labor is equal for each commodity produced of each labor supplier. • The marginal "rupee" cost of each unit of resources is equal to the marginal value productivity of each commodity. A social welfare function provides a kind of social preference based on only narrowly defined individual utility functions, whereas in others it includes cardinal measures of social welfare not aggregated from narrow individual utility functions. 7 The utility function expresses utility as a function of consumption of real goods (in pounds, gallons, kilograms, litres) as opposed to nominal goods (in rupees, dollars, euros). A utility is a numerical rating assigned to every possible outcome that faces a decision-maker may be faced with. In a choice between several alternative prospects, the one with the highest utility is always preferred. To qualify as a true utility scale however, the rating must be such that the utility of any uncertain prospect is equal to the expected value (the mathematical expectation) of the utilities of all its possible outcomes (which could be either "final" outcomes or uncertain prospects themselves). 8 In the literature on the issue of pricing of public utilities, a number of theoretical variants have been discussed. They are named as: cost-based pricing, cost sharing, efficient pricing, declining block tariff, demand compatible prices, flat rate tariff, fully distributed cost, fully separating tariff, n-part tariff, optimal non-uniform price schedule, optimal Pareto dominating incentive compatible tariff, optimal two part tariff, optional tariff, Pareto dominating incentive compatible tariff, Ramsey uniform pricing, etc. 50 The second principle relates to efficiency in resource allocation. He gives a clear, intuitive explanation of the willingness to pay for incremental output with costs that lead to efficient use of productive capacity. Further, he recognizes that this may lead to determination of price at a level lower than AC. This gives leeway to fix the charges according to what the traffic will bear in order to cover the costs. In this sense, Clark anticipated the idea of Ramsey pricing. Of course, the concepts of issues like outlays, capital or current etc gave rise to further complications. Clark’s MC pricing policy gained favour among economists. It was the basis for price discrimination in specific utilities, given the existing target groups and the prevailing Government’s philosophy. However, the MC theory has a number of restrictive assumptions, which are also its limitations 9 . These are summarized below: 1. The demand for the service should respond to price changes; that is, it should not be perfectly price-inelastic; 2. There should be perfect information on the part of the users regarding future costs and price changes; 3. No externalities should result from the provision or consumption of the service; 4. There should be no distortion anywhere else in the economy; 5. The prices of inputs used in the production of the service, and the prices of substitutes or complements to the service should not be distorted by taxes, subsidies, or externalities; 6. Whenever the rule results in a financial surplus or deficit for the service, nondistorting subsidy or tax schemes should be made available so that it is possible to absorb the surplus or deficit without affecting the allocation of resources in the economy; 7. There should be no administrative or transaction costs associated with implementing this rule; and 8. Production should be efficient so that the cost of producing a given unit is minimized. Inspite of these limitations, it is important to note that the MC principle remains relevant in utility pricing under various conditions, as are given below: 9 Bahl, R.W. and J.F. Linn. 1992. Urban Public Finance in Developing Countries. World Bank. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 51 i. The MC principle is concerned with the opportunity costs incurred by greater use of a service. This may or may not equal historical costs because various features (such as economies of scale, technological advances, natural resource constraints, factor prices and service standards) may change the MC over time. ii. Consumers should be charged a uniform rate for the services consumed unless the service necessitates the imposition of a differential MC. Rising (or falling) user charges may not be justifiable on grounds of efficiency because the MC must be matched by the price. Quantity discounts or surcharges could, however, be justified on grounds of efficiency. iii. The MC pricing policy needs to be adjusted during the inflationary periods. If the underlying real cost structure does not change over time and if a user charge has been correctly set at a particular time, rapid inflation could make the nominal user charge diverge considerably from the efficient charge over time. iv. If the demand for the public service shows some price-elasticity, then efficiency will be affected irrespective of whether or not the service is priced at MC. If the demand for a service is perfectly or almost perfectly inelastic, the quantity consumed will not change in response to a change in price. Therefore, the use of economic resources will not be affected by the price and subsequently, no loss or gain in efficiency will result from setting prices above or below MC. v. User charges might differ in developing and developed countries. The developed countries could have more efficient user charges to check the excess provision of public services (which is encouraged by pricing policies geared to satisfy non-economic objectives) or to control environmental hazards, particularly water and air pollution 10 . Given that it is not optimal to set utility prices equal to MC while covering resulting deficits by discretionary taxation, there are two alternative feasible pricing policies that can be adopted. Boiteux Pricing: The first, adopted by Boiteux 11 , was to consider each utility as having its own profit constraint, and then search for welfare optimal prices. It led to peak load pricing, where Boiteux 12 assumed that MC pricing is optimal, and derived the structure of MC based prices when demand varied cyclically over a time period, given the fixed capacity. The assumption of constant returns implies that these prices should break even. These results can be extended to encompass Ramsey pricing policy. 10 Kneese, A.V. and C.L. Schultze. 1975. Pollution, Prices, and Public Policy. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. 11 Boiteux, M. 1971. “On the Management of Public Monopolies Subject to Budget Constraints”. Journal of Economic Theory. 3: 219-40. 12 Boiteux, M. 1960. “Peak Load Pricing”. Journal of Business. 33, (2), April: 157-79. 52 Ramsey Pricing: The second is the Ramsey theory 13 that sees the problem as one of optimal commodity taxation. There is a Government revenue requirement, which may be much greater than the amount required just to cover public utility deficits, and the problem is to find taxes, or mark ups on MCs, for all goods (except a numeraire), that generate the required revenue with minimum aggregate welfare loss. Now, Boiteux’s problem can be viewed as a sub-case of Ramsey’s: if the utility’s deficits are to be met out of taxation, then its optimal prices are not necessarily those which lead to break even for the utility itself, but are simply those that incorporate the optimal commodity taxes. That is, the revenue generated by a utility when its prices embody optimal taxes could be greater or less than its costs. The question that the Ramsey raises is whether the Government monopolist should set its prices to maximize social welfare (efficiency), subject to an overall budget constraint? The rule states that the price markup should be inverse to the price elasticity of demand. The more elastic is the demand for the product, the smaller will be the price markup. This is applicable to public utilities or for regulation of natural monopolies. In other words, the percentage deviation of the price of a good from its MC should be inversely related to its elasticity of demand. Ramsey pricing is a linear pricing scheme designed for the multi-product natural monopolist. Theory of Average Cost (AC) Pricing: This refers to making the product price equal to the AC of production. The AC pricing guarantees the public utility a normal profit but as the determined price is greater than MC, the public utility is not operating according to the rule of efficiency. This approach estimates the total financial cost of providing a particular service and divides the total cost by the number of units being provided. In doing so, when costs decline as output increases, the price will be too high and the output remains much lesser than what the society really wants. Conversely, when costs increase as output expands, the price will be too low; too much of the service in question will be demanded and resources will be misallocated. This is especially true if the "excess" demand at the unduly low price is taken as an indication that output should be increased - for example, by new investment. The AC pricing will be efficient if unit costs are constant, so that marginal and average costs are equal. The second problem with AC pricing (assuming costs are not constant) is that the setting of such prices effectively requires estimating responsiveness of demand to price changes. Suppose a particular service, such as a national park, has previously 13 Ramsey, F.P. 1927. “A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation”. Economic Journal. 37, March: 4761. 53 been supplied free, or at a charge well below a realistic price. Assume that the variable costs of operating that particular park (i.e. the costs to keep it open and operating at some level) - can be estimated without great difficulty. The number of persons using the park is also known. Clearly, dividing this cost by the number of people is unlikely to result in full "cost-recovery”. Setting average prices to recover operating costs thus requires not only information on how unit costs change as the number of users change, but also on how the number of users will change as prices change. Such information is not easy to obtain, and even if it is available, the resulting prices are not likely to provide an efficient allocation of resources (because of the first problem mentioned above) or any useful information on whether access to the park should be extended or eliminated (because the "fixed cost" aspect has not been factored into the calculation). However, in spite of these difficulties in estimation, AC pricing is probably the most common way of setting user charges. Moreover, the "costs" taken into account are usually financial and not social, as discussed above. Presumably, this inefficient practice is followed because such prices are easier to calculate and compelling to powerful client groups, in spite of the economists' preference for the MC pricing approach. Such reasoning is understandable, and in many cases, AC pricing is acceptable. Price Discrimination: In practice, the above stated principles may not yield desirable solutions. Therefore, a mix of these price policies is applied for different utilities. This could result in arbitrariness in pricing policy. Refinement of MC and AC pricing policies leads to the development of other models of utility pricing or price discrimination. These theories consider all the dimensions of public service output and costs, variations in costs across space, time, and consumer classes. These take into account externalities, distortions in input and output prices, imperfect consumer information, administrative and transaction costs, capital indivisibility, efficiency in production and fiscal considerations. These also take into consideration the fact that full cost pricing has an impact on multi-part tariffs, uniform tariffs, as well as on income distribution. Some of these price theories are: Economic Pricing: Saleth and Dinar 14 propounded their price theory in the context of water pricing. They argued that economic pricing of water is necessary not only for improving the financial viability and efficiency in water use but also for providing incentive for private initiatives, especially in the form of inter-household and inter-sectoral water exchanges and joint ownership and management of ground water wells and other water supply sources by user groups. Their results reveal that under the existing price structure, characterized by increasing intervals between 14 Saleth, R.M. and A. Dinar. 1997. Satisfying Urban Thirst, Water Supply Augmentation and Pricing Policy in Hyderabad City, India. World Bank Technical Paper No. 395. Washington DC: The World Bank. 54 successive consumption slabs and slab-specific constant water rates, the water consumption decision is not affected by the MC price but only by the AC pricing. Another example of water pricing is the declining block tariff. Nordin 15 suggested it in his analysis of the water demand function given the block tariffs. This theory is applied only when aggregate data (values of marginal price and price differences faced by the average user) are compared with the theoretically correct data. The latter uses the average marginal price of the block and the average price difference, these averages being weighted by the proportion of users per block. The availability of data on the proportion of users per block also permits the explicit modeling of the choice of block. The results show that, in the sample analyzed, the values of price elasticity under the traditional specification and the more innovative one are not significantly different. Fully Distributed Cost Pricing: User charges could be based on fully distributed costs (FDC) pricing method. Under this method, regulators allocate shared production costs to individual services. Each service is then required to generate revenues that will cover all of the costs associated with that service. Braeutigam 16 has argued that there is no sound economic rationale for FDC pricing and that this practice has economic consequence for regulated industries. In practice, there are three variants of FDC rules: First is the distribution of shared costs on the basis of some common indicator of utilization or consumption 17 . In this method, known as the relative output method, shared costs are allocated in proportion to the number of units of output of each service. 15 Nordin used aggregate data from North-West of Spain for the analysis. See Nordin, J.A. 1976. “A Proposed Modification on Taylor’s Demand–Supply Analysis: Comment”. The Bell Journal of Economics. 7(2): 719–721. 16 Braeutigam, R.R. 1980. “An Analysis of Fully Distributed Cost Pricing in Regulated Industries”. Bell Journal of Economics. 11 (1) Spring: 182-196. This paper examines the economic consequences of allocating common costs by (1) gross revenues, (2) directly attributable costs, and (3) relative output levels (such as ton-miles) to determine fully distributed cost prices for regulated firms. The analysis characterizes FDC tariffs by examining the nature of the economic inefficiency associated with the rules and explains how opportunities for entry by unregulated firms might change if Ramsey optional pricing was used instead of FDC pricing. 17 Kahn, A. 1970. The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions. Vol 1. New York: Wiley and Sons. 55 The second approach is known as attributable cost 18 method. These are the costs, which cease if a particular service is discontinued. The third method, known as gross revenue approach or the relative money value method, requires allocation of shared costs in proportion to the gross revenues generated by each service. A variance of these approaches may be used depending upon the nature of the services. These variants have certain features that need to be kept in mind: 1) FDC bears no direct relationship to MCs; hence, there is no basis for economic efficiency in FDC pricing. 2) There exists no unique acceptable rule. Friedlender 19 has noted that there are various ways of ‘pro-rating’ the common or joint costs, but all of them have an arbitrary element and hence, are dangerous to use in prescribing rates. 3) On grounds of economic efficiency, it may be desirable to set a price for some service so that the revenues generated by that service do not cover its FDC. 4) As the determination of FDC is somewhat arbitrary, there is no economic basis for concluding that a service is being subsidized by other services if its revenues are less than its FDC. 5) FDC pricing is anti-competitive since it prevents a supplier from offering a service at a proposed tariff less than an FDC price; particularly if the proposed tariff exceeds the MC of providing the service. And 6) There is circular reasoning behind the FDC practice. Tariffs, which are determined to be appropriate at a given time, may depend on the existing levels of output or revenues, and these, in turn, depend on previous tariffs. Thus, FDC may depend on the acceptance of a prior tariff structure. Also, it is important to note that there are some issues that have to be kept in mind with regard to FDC pricing policy. Thus, should the FDC of a service reflect the extent to which the historical total costs of the firm were affected by the presence of 18 Attributable cost is the cost, which ceases if a particular service is discontinued. Calculating attributable cost requires identification of all network elements that would become redundant if the service was discontinued. Attributable cost is the cost inherent in maintaining these network elements. A yardstick for predatory prices based on attributable or incremental cost makes economic sense: should an undertaking not even cover the specific cost of the specific network elements that production of a certain service requires, it would be better off not supplying the service. Continuing the service goes against the economic interest of the service provider and forecloses efficient competitors. On the other hand, a standard based on attributable cost does not aim to destroy synergies or economies of scope that a multi-service undertaking achieves in providing several services, on a common infrastructure. 19 Friedlender, A.F. 1969. The Dilemma of Freight Transport Regulation. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution. 56 the service? On the other hand, should current replacement costs be used instead of historical costs? Subsidy-free Pricing: Another variant of this pricing system is subsidy-free prices. The constrained market pricing approach to regulate monopolies maintains that prices should be subsidy-free, lying between the expansive bounds of stand-alone and incremental costs. Using a simple two-good/two-period model of a monopolist subject to a zero profit constraint, it is shown that subsidy-free prices are those which rise to the amortized opportunity cost of the currently optimal asset configuration required to meet both current and future demand. In some circumstances, this reasoning provides justification for accelerated depreciation. Such inter-temporal subsidy-free prices recognize that the stand-alone cost of existing assets to current consumers depends on the value of those assets to future consumers. Hence, if a feasible resale price for the fixed costs of capacity exists within or between the periods, then inter-temporal stand-alone costs and inter-temporal incremental costs are driven to equality. Application of FDC pricing is seen in Jha et al 20 where cross-subsidy-free/First Best Prices policy has been applied to postal services in India. This service has the characteristic of joint production of several items with increasing returns to scale leading to the emergence of a ‘natural’ monopoly. In this case, each item must have adequate incentive to stay with the ‘monopoly’ or alternatively, be able to face the competition from another agency that may be supplying the same item or a subset of such items. In this situation, it may be difficult or even impossible to a priori allocate the costs amongst the various products. The thumb-rule in such a situation is that cross-subsidy-free prices for a public utility with joint production are the First Best Prices or Pareto optimal prices. The issues involved in this are (a) Cost sharing: The prices of various items of a multi-product are such that they cover the full cost of production. (b) Rescaling: If the scales of measurement of commodities are changed, then the prices are changed accordingly. (c) Consistency: Each unit of the same good has the same price, if prices depend only upon cost functions and not demand functions. (d) Positivity: If a cost function ‘A’ increases as rapidly as the cost function ‘B’ with respect to quantities of commodities, then the prices determined for ‘A’ should be at least as high as those determined for ‘B’. And, (e) Additivity: If a cost function can be broken down into two components say A and B (e.g., management and production), then the calculation of the price 20 Jha, R.S., M.N. Murthy and S. Paul. 1990. Pricing of Postal Services in India. New Delhi: National Institute of Public Finance and Policy. 57 (determined by the cost function) for any level of production can be done by adding the price determined by A and B respectively for that level of production. The cross-subsidy-free prices can be computed given the long run cost functions of a multi-product public utility. The second best or Ramsey prices are not cross-subsidy-free. For a welfare maximising public utility with a balanced budget, these prices are inevitable. Given the alternative sources of revenue like commodity taxes and income taxes to finance the public utility production, the welfare maximising prices for such utility services may not be globally optimal. The social cost of raising revenue, through prices (of public utility services, and other public sector commodities) and taxes (income taxes, commodity taxes etc.), to fund public utility production have to be considered while fixing globally optimal utility prices. They have suggested a pricing scheme for public utility services that takes cross-subsidy-free prices as the “first best producer prices” and the subsidised or tax inclusive prices as the “consumer prices”. In an economy having a public utility with increasing returns to scale and a private sector with constant returns to scale, crosssubsidy-free prices for the public utility and prices that are equal to MC (constant) for private sector commodities are the Pareto optimal prices 21 for that given level of production of public utility services. Given these prices for public utility services and private sector commodities, the second best prices a’ la Ramsey can be determined by the welfare maximising Government with revenue, efficiency and equity objectives. Demand-Compatible Prices: In the case of mixed cost allocation problems, i.e. joint costs, there are two types of heterogeneous outputs: divisible and indivisible output. There are a set of axioms, which characterize a family of price mechanisms for consumption goods, including MC prices and Aumann-Shapley prices 22 . By strengthening one of the axioms, MC prices are characterized by requiring that cost is shared as per the Aumann-Shapley price policy of cost sharing mechanism. It is derived from a set of natural axioms. The model considers one producer with a given technology who has fixed input prices and produces a finite number of consumption goods. Thus, a unique vector can be derived as the cost function that describes the MC of producing a given vector of consumption goods. Uniform Pricing: Brito and Oakland 23 have come out with three principal findings. 21 Pareto optimality or efficiency is referred to as the efficient allocation (system, taxes or prices) where no person can be made better off without making another person worse off. Sometimes efficiency is referred to as Pareto optimality after the Italian economist Vilfred Pareto (1848-1923), who first developled the formulation. 22 Aumann-Shapley price system is the mechanism of sharing costs among various products. 23 Brito, DL and WH Oakland. 1980. “On the Monopolistic Provision of Excludable Public Goods”. The American Economic Review. Vol. 11, No. 1 (September): 691-706. 58 (a) Whether or not it is constrained to a single uniform price, a monopoly will produce a sub-optimal level of public goods and inefficiently exclude some consumers from part of the output actually produced. Three principal conclusions of the uniform price model are: (i) Consumers will be divided into two classes: those, which are rationed by price, and those rationed by output. (ii) Only those consumers who are rationed by output will be relevant to the output expansion decision, and their demands will be reflected by price rather than marginal revenue. (iii)The solution will not be Pareto efficient. The allocation of existing output will be inefficient because some consumers are excluded from consuming some of the total amount of the good available. The level of output will be sub-optimal because the profits of the firm fail to reflect the excess demand price premiums of some of the consumers. (b) In general, a monopolist will find it profitable to vary price with the level of the service provided to a particular customer. In a wide range of cases, the marginal price will be declining with respect to units of the service provided. (c) If prices vary with units of service, the monopoly price schedule will lie above the corresponding competitive price schedule and the monopoly output will fall short of the competitive level of output. Non-Uniform Pricing: While MC and AC pricing theories recommend one price for the services to be provided, a frequent assumption made in non-uniform pricing relates to the fact that local maximizing conditions need to be met exactly once for each purchasing consumer; no consumer can be indifferent between two nonadjacent usage levels. Each consumer then responds to a change in marginal price only by incrementally reducing his usage. More realistically, maximizing conditions are sometimes twice met by some interior users, who can be indifferent between nonadjacent usage levels and may, therefore, jump discretely if marginal prices change at either level. A monopolist's generalized price schedule may be derived under these circumstances and shows that marginal price may fall below MC. Multi-part Tariff: A basic principle behind restructuring of rates is to increase economic efficiency. Changes in rate structures are a necessary element in increasing economic efficiency. An efficient rate structure requires that prices paid by the consumer more closely reflect the MC of the services provided. A multi-part tariff is one mechanism by which efficient pricing can be implemented. A multi-part tariff reduces the perverse effect that existing rate structures have on the incentives of regulated utilities and their affiliates to provide energy efficient services. As long as marginal rates exceed MC, utilities will incur a loss when their customers conserve more energy. 59 There is a problem in implementing a multi-part tariff. Here, the fixed portion of the tariff prevents customers, who might otherwise realize benefits in excess of MCs, from hooking up. This does not help in raising the overall economic efficiency. Therefore, there might be justification for lower fixed charges for low-income customers on the basis of efficiency rather than on equity. Two Part Tariff: Criticizing MC pricing when losses had to be covered out of taxation, Coase 24 proposed two-part pricing as an alternative. This is a price discrimination technique in which the price of a product or service is composed of two parts - a lump-sum fee as well as a per-unit charge. As with all price discrimination techniques, it may only occur in partially or fully monopolistic markets. It is designed to enable the firm to capture more consumer surplus than it otherwise would have in a non-discriminating pricing environment. The lump-sum fee charged varies depending on the homogeneity of demand. The rational firm will set the per unit charge above or equal to the MC of production, and below or equal to the price the firm would charge in a perfect monopoly. This two-part tariff price policy is still a form of price discrimination. An important feature is that the product or service offered by the firm must be identical to all consumers. The price charged may vary, but this is not due to different costs borne by the firm, as this would otherwise mean a differentiated product. Myopic Pricing Rules: Gronau 25 , suggested that congestion and road damage is associated, in general, with different types of vehicles. He analysed the user charges in the context of the road sector. Congestion is an urban phenomenon associated with private cars. It is mainly the heavy vehicles on inter-urban roads which cause road damage. The different externalities call for different charges on heavy vehicles and private cars. In the case of road services, it is useful to note that cost of providing road differs according to its use. Economic efficiency calls for charging different prices for these services, based on short-run MCs. These costs vary by type and density of traffic, and according to the maintenance and investment policies adopted by the road authority. Whether or not the charges, set equal to short-run MCs, cover maintenance and capital costs depends on the returns to scale in the production of road services; the returns to scope; and the maintenance and capital outlay policies adopted. In simple terminology, a road offers two basic services: access and loading capacity. The MC of producing these services depend on two different attributes of the road: its capacity (width) and its durability (strength). The wider and stronger the road, the cheaper it is to produce vehicle services. Different users (for example, private cars and heavy vehicles) require these services in different proportions and should be charged different prices for using them. 24 Coase, R. H. 1946. "The Marginal Cost Controversy". Economica, New Series. Vol 13(51): 169-182. Gronau, R. 1994. “Fuel Taxes and Road-User Charges in LDCs: Some Lessons from Sub-Saharan Africa”. The Journal of Transport Economics and Policy. September: 255-273. 25 60 In the context of developing countries, the factor most often emphasized is the loading factor. The heavier the vehicle, the more will be the road deterioration. This results in an increase in vehicles operating costs to all users. The damaging effect of a vehicle depends on the road authority’s maintenance and capital outlay policy. The damage can be contained by an appropriate maintenance policy or by building a stronger road; or it can go unchecked if maintenance and capital outlay are insensitive to road conditions. In view of this, the user charges for different types of transport should be determined on the basis of congestion and damage done to the road. Spot Pricing: It is, of course, impossible to forecast future demand and capacity availability with perfect certainty. This, therefore, raises the possibility that, given rigid maximum capacity in the short run, demand at the planned price may be greater or less than capacity. Where price is perfectly flexible in the short run, ‘spot pricing’ can be used to maintain the equality between capacity and demand. However, this is subject to technological, regulatory or political constraints which prevent the spot price from being used to fulfill its rationing function to a sufficient extent. Therefore, there will be excess capacity in low demand/ low capacity regions, and non-price rationing in high demand/ low capacity regions. Concept of Costs It is clear from the foregoing discussions that critical to pricing is the concept of costs. Costs as viewed by economists (advocating MC pricing) are quite different from the costs facing public sector managers, even those operating activities already structured as "cost centres". The notion of cost in financial accounting is simply identifiable monetary outlays incurred in the process of carrying out a particular activity. Such costs include wages, rent, utilities, transportation, supplies etc. These costs reflect actual financial outlays made in some particular time period. It can be difficult to allocate such costs to any particular service activity. Cost accountants have developed various methods, albeit sometimes arbitrary, to deal with the problem of allocating such joint or overhead costs. Economic costs are not simply accounting costs. The fundamental economic concept is of opportunity cost, or the value of the benefits that could have been obtained had the inputs been used for another purpose. From this perspective, the cost of a park does not simply consist of tangible, recorded construction and operating costs. Instead, the relevant cost is the (highest) value that the land could have realized had it been used for some other purpose, such as logging or residential development. Thus, an effective MC pricing policy requires estimating of social or opportunity costs. This may be a difficult task, as estimating the MC of another unit 61 of a particular service requires identifying all additional costs resulting from this incremental expansion 26 . Problems of Measurability Even without conceptual problems, there may be problems of measurability. Relevant market prices can often be found - for example, the value of land used for a park if it were to be logged, or built on. However, such prices can be used to measure socially relevant MC only if it can be assumed that market prices are good approximations to MC prices. For this assumption to be valid, the market from which the information is derived should be close to perfectly competitive - that is, private sellers set prices close to MC (including a "normal" rate of return on capital). If MC-based user charges can be calculated, and applied, by definition the amount charged for providing an additional unit of any particular service will just equal the benefit that society, as a whole, derives from the provision of that unit. In practice, however, it is often necessary to estimate the effects of price changes on demand to determine the desirable level of such charges. While there are various methods of obtaining this information - for example, by using market information on substitute or complementary activities (e.g., travel costs in the case of recreational facilities) or by carefully structured surveys (e.g., contingent valuation analysis) - it is generally more difficult to get reliable information on demand than on cost. Further, there are several additional issues that must be settled. One of the most important is the possible inclusion of “fixed costs" (investment costs). In principle, short-run MC (SRMC) prices should be imposed to ensure efficient allocation of resources. When such charges are used, it must be assumed that the size of a facility is optimal. This condition requires one of two improbabilities: the initial investment decision was based on correct social cost-benefit principles, taking pricing into account. Otherwise, the SRMC prices will be altered as usage changes. That is, when there is excess capacity, no charge will be imposed. However, as the usage level rises, user charges will reflect increasing congestion costs. Thus, when the time comes to replace the facility, the funds will be available to do so. The problem with this solution is twofold. First, congestion costs are difficult to estimate. Second, even if such costs can be estimated, established user charges tend to be difficult to alter without major political and administrative effort. Such efforts are unlikely to be successful in raising prices to pay for a deteriorating level of service. However, if long run MC (LRMC) is used in the initial pricing calculation, overbuilt facilities will be even more under-used and managers will not have demand information with which to work. 26 Congestion, for example, in transport facilities clearly gives rise to real social costs, but it may be hard to convert such costs of waiting into monetary values. This must be done, however, in the process of determining efficient prices. 62 Many public activities face decreasing average costs. That is, as output expands, the cost per unit falls. If average costs are decreasing, then MC must, by definition, be below average costs. There are facilities with large "sunk" costs and high economies of scale- such as hydro-electric plants and telecommunication networks. In such cases, applying MC pricing means the user charge will be less than average cost, which in turn means that efficient charges will result in financial deficits. Properly designed user charges will often require the collection of complex and difficult-to-obtain information. How costly is it for the manager to charge? 27 Indeed, the costs of pricing may be so high as to make it unfeasible to apply user charges. The costs of obtaining the necessary detailed cost and demand information may exceed any conceivable benefits from applying even the best-designed charges. In all these cases, such costs (like the actual costs of implementing charges and the (less visible) costs of ensuring compliance) should be factored into the final ‘price’ determination. Costs of many public sector activities - for example, admitting a person to a facility in the off season - may readily be calculated. But the cost of collecting the charge may exceed this amount. If so, no charge should be levied. Every road could be a toll road, but the high cost of collecting all those tolls would make it impractical. Designing User Charges Certain characteristics of monopoly pricing have to be reviewed before designing user charges, since the Government is deemed to be a natural monopolist in providing certain public utilities. These are: (i) In order to maximize profits, the firm must set the price of the last unit of output equal to MC of production. (ii) The monopolist will choose a level of output, which is sub-optimal in the Pareto sense. This implies that consumers would be capable of bribing the firm to produce additional units of output. They cannot do so, however, because this would require personalized prices. The firm, by assumption, must charge the same price schedule to all customers. (iii) If income function of the consumer is continuous and it is desirable to exclude some individuals entirely from the consumption of the public good, the profit-maximizing price schedule does not contain a fixed charge. 27 That is, to collect the information required to derive an appropriate user charge regime, and the cost of collecting the user charge. 63 (iv) If the utility function is separable and the density is differentiable and non-decreasing; consumption of the private good will be strictly nonincreasing in the time period and the marginal price will be falling. (v) The monopoly marginal price schedule lies somewhere above and nowhere below the competitive solution. (vi) Monopoly output will always fall short of competitive output. It states that underproduction is made even worse by the monopoly provision. The problem of under-utilization is also exacerbated because of the higher prices; monopoly will result in greater exclusion from the stock of goods in existence. While the result that monopoly is less efficient than competition is not new in economic analysis, it is important that it be rigorously demonstrated in the case of excludable public goods. Although user charges are sometimes perceived as a form of taxation, they differ clearly in that they are linked to specific benefits which are over and above those enjoyed by the general public. In other words, taxes are used to fund programs for all citizens, whereas user fees are directed to recovering the costs of specific private goods and services. A policy that emphasizes user charges is not designed to obtain revenue, or even to obtain revenue in a way perceived to be fair. Rather, it is designed to redefine Government priorities by incorporating more feedback from citizens with respect to the services they want and for which they are willing to pay. From this perspective, what matters is not just to impose charges but also to levy the correct charges. Let us sum up the rules. First Best Solutions: Taxation and subsidization: Prices be set equal to marginal costs, and revenue shortfalls need to be recovered through non-distortionary taxation policies. It may be criticized on grounds of (i) an inadvertent redistribution of income, (ii) income taxes that are distortionary, and (iii) misallocation of resources. The Coase Two Part Tariff: each consumer would be charged a single price according to P=MC, but would also pay a lump-sum or fixed charge for the opportunity to be able to buy any unit of the service. It is also criticized on account of misinterpretation of the problems accruing from increasing returns to scale. Second Best Solutions: (i) Ramsey prices: Attempt to maximize welfare subject to full-cost recovery, through the use of inverse elasticity rule, i.e. charging consumers with inelastic demands a higher price relative to consumers with elastic demands. The use of Ramsey pricing may lead to problems of equity. (ii) Nonlinear pricing: Refers to any case in which the tariff is not strictly proportional to the quantity purchased. Consumers act as price takers, given the pricing schedules: If offered a menu of prices and corresponding charges, each consumer chooses a preferred quantity and pays the associated charge. 64 An additional factor in determining user charges is the cost of changing public prices once they have been set. So long as an agency is in the public sphere, the price it sets inevitably reflects the outcome of a political and administrative process and not a pure "market" or economic process. Thus, user charges are a political tool and hence, inherently "sticky" or hard to change. Once set, they tend to prevail until political circumstances permit or compel change. This situation is observed most readily when prices are first set on a service that was previously provided free, but this also applies in varying degrees to all changes in public prices. For this reason, it is particularly important to set economically efficient prices. Conclusion It may be realised that the aim of the cost recovery policy should be: to have efficient allocation of resources (i.e. to eliminate the excess demand that often exists with "free goods", given the supply and demand); and to promote equity in financing Government programs, mandatory or otherwise, by charging beneficiaries an equal or higher rate than those enjoyed by the general public. This may allow a greater share of general tax money to be devoted to activities that benefit the general taxpayer, or to reduce the debt. It may also facilitate improvements in the delivery of specific costrecovered services; and to earn a fair return for the public for access to or exploitation of the publicly-owned or controlled resources. The principles of cost recovery may be based on certain normative principles: (i) Equity- implying that beneficiaries of services should contribute towards their cost. (ii) Efficiency- that is market tests of the demand for services should help determine the quantity and quality of their supply. (iii) Accountability and service standards- which imply that it is the cost recovery that emphasizes the accountability of Government departments to fee-payers for the delivery of services as per the overall public policy objectives of the service and the explicit standards set for its improvement. (iv) Partnership, i.e. the decision to produce a service through the application of user fees implies consultation and partnership with beneficiaries both at the stage of fee setting and in the ongoing management of the program, leading to satisfaction in the accountability and standard of the service. (v) Cumulative impact- which involves setting fee levels; departments and agencies reviewing and taking into account the effects on clients of not only of the specific fees they propose, but also the cumulative direct and indirect impact of other federal fee setting activities. Tariffs should be transparent and should not affect the quality of the service. There must be penalties for sub-standard quality and service; cross subsidies should 65 be removed from the tariff structure; and targeted explicit subsidies for the needy should be clearly targetted. The tariff structure should provide flexibility to users. Given the politico-economic situation of an economy, it is difficult to apply a purely economic rational policy for user charges. If the consideration is that the service providing units, not covered by the budgetary mechanism, should be fully responsible for maintaining the desired level of service delivery, then it should be obligatory on the part of the Government to compensate them for the possible losses due to the subsidised element of cost recovery. If the Government has to maximize its objective function of social welfare and utility, it has to share the burden of financing it e.g. minor irrigation, education and health are cases of merit goods but are also the inputs for economic development and human resource development, which affect the overall development of the economy indirectly. The variations of practices in cost recovery policy coupled with the stated objective functions of respective States bring out the differences in cost recovery ratios (norms). It would be interesting to see what would be the likely fiscal scenario in the States if there were uniformity in such a policy. Two extreme options may be, either to follow the leader or adhere to the rule of averages. The simulated exercise may help in some convergence of policies and practices. It could also teach a lesson to others who do not tread the chosen policy path. 66 4 Revenue Realization from Non-tax Sources The trends in revenue from non-tax sources (Chapter 2) clearly bring out the need to improve the growth of non-tax revenues in most of the Indian States. The comparative picture that emerges from a study of non-tax sources in different countries also indicates the need for giving a boost to the efforts at mobilizing non-tax sources in India. The fact remains that most of the user charges for Government services in Indian States are fixed at an abysmally low level or remained practically non-existent. The theories of utility pricing (Chapter 3) point out that an efficient allocation of resources and equity in financing Government services is possible. Government is required to focus on cost recovery for its services. While it is important to aim at appropriate cost recovery, it is useful to keep in purview the following features that characterize the services provided by the Government: (1) These services are characterized by externalities. The goods and services provided by the Government benefit the society as a whole, irrespective of whether these are being targeted at any specific individual or group. These services also have the quality of ‘nonrivalness’, i.e. the consumption or enjoyment of these goods and services by one individual or one group does not affect their availability and satisfaction for the others. In addition, the goods and services provided by the Government enjoy scale of economies in their provision. Efficient production or supply of these goods is not viable for small private producers. Hence, these services are treated as a natural monopoly of the Government. (2) There is an unending debate on the nature of goods and services provided by the Government. While the benefits of public goods are expected to accrue to the society as a whole, all the goods and services provided by the Government cannot be treated as pure public goods-- the benefits of these goods and services are enjoyed by both the targeted and nontargeted groups. Hence, it is difficult to classify Government goods and services as pure public goods or quasi-public (or mixed goods). Although many of the goods and services provided by the State Governments may not be ‘pure public goods’ and could accrue to non-targeted groups in the society, it is a widely held belief that it is the targeted sections who enjoy better access to the services. Hence, part of the cost of these services should be recovered from the target groups by the imposition of appropriate user charges. However, the ‘marginal cost pricing’ principle, generally applicable to pricing of ‘private’ goods and services, may not be appropriate for pricing such goods and services as this would imply negligible or zero recovery through user charges 1 . This view has got an added impetus with the structural reforms adopted in the country. The trend is towards reducing the quantum of subsidy and levying appropriate user charges for the provision of public services. User charges will be determined according to the economic status of the user and the type of the commodity. The user charge will be such that the cost is met and the price of the commodity does not lead to over-consumption of such services and hence, to a wasteful use of scarce resources. Issues in Determination of User Charges The million-dollar question is how does the Government fix user charges for non-tax sources? Appropriate user charges serve the twin purposes of having a rational non-tax structure and generating greater means to achieve economic growth. Irrational structure of nontax sources causes adverse economic effects, invalidating the growth objectives. From the point of view of economics, therefore, one has to keep in mind the objectives of fixation of user charges. • Firstly, the objective of equity advocates equalization of benefit to each segment of the society. If the marginal benefits are not equal, then the society’s total welfare can be increased by reassigning the service usage amongst the different sections of the society; • Secondly, objective of ensuring consumer acceptability refers to having a simple pricing system, which is easily comprehensible and acceptable to the consumers of the services at large. Therefore, the pricing system should not be complex; • Thirdly, the concept of administrative feasibility points out that discrimination of rates should be administratively feasible and hence, there should be a limit to the rate differentiation; and 1 In the literature on public finance, it is largely accepted that the marginal cost pricing principle is applicable to the provision of Government services so long as (i) the benefits of the service accrue to the masses, and the marginal expenditure exceeds the marginal cost and (ii) the marginal benefits of financing the service is equal to the possible marginal benefit from other competing investments. See for details infra Chapter 3. 68 • Finally, environmental considerations suggest that the pricing system should be such that it encourages and promotes the efficient use of environmental resources. To fulfill the above objectives, the Government has to adopt an economically rational structure of non-tax sources that may not be palatable politically. A popularly elected Government, therefore, has to adopt a balance between the two. The determination of user charges largely depends upon the degree of publicness of these goods. If the goods and services provided by the Government were purely “public” in nature, it would be difficult to recover their full cost; if these goods and services are “private” in nature, the willingness to bear the cost will be almost zero. Also, in quasi-public services, the unit cost of providing the services depends upon the amount of funds the society is willing to pay and the form financing of the service. The willingness to pay for the service will depend upon the usefulness of the service; the more useful the service, the higher will be the willingness to pay by the society. Actual Cost Recovery The actual cost to the Government of providing the public service will be reflected by: • budgetary allocation from the general pool of Government resources, reflecting the society’s willingness to absorb the cost through the voting process; • actual cost recovery through user charges; and • unrecovered costs due to market inefficiencies. The actual revenue realization as a percent of revenue expenditure (RR/RE) 2 , however, varies according to the type of service. The Government will have to look into the preferences of the society, by making use of empirical surveys. Such surveys (i) reveal the overall preferences of the society for each service given the choice between the financing of the service through budgetary allocations and through the user charges 3 , and (ii) help in making comparisons between the actual RR/RE through user charges and the desired level of RR/RE. In this analysis of the efforts of the States in collecting appropriate user charges for services provided, the study presents an estimate of the percentage share of revenue realized (RR) from a service to the revenue expenditure (RE) incurred on providing that service. An attempt is then made to compare RR/RE of different services among the States. 2 Hereafter, Revenue Receipts as percent of Revenue Expenditure will be denoted as RR/RE. In Berkeley, California (USA), for example, a survey was conducted to find out from the society whether the BART (train service like Metro in Delhi) railway line be underground (requiring the society to pay more) or over ground (incurring less cost and consequently lower user charges). The society preferred that it be underground in the city areas. 3 69 The study, however, confines its scope to only those non-tax sources, which originate from the administrative departments and departmental undertakings of a non-commercial nature. Therefore, sources such as interest, profits and dividends arising from the States’ commercial undertakings are beyond its scope. As stated in chapter 1, the non-tax sources covered in the study include some select administrative non-tax receipts from general, social, and economic services. In view of the strategic importance of some of the services in the overall non-tax sources, the study attempts to measure RR/RE for the following ten services: (1) Public works, (2) Education, sports, art & culture, (3) Medical, public health and family welfare, (4) Water supply and sanitation, (5) Forestry and wild life, (6) Major and medium irrigation, (7) Minor irrigation, (8) Industries, (9) Mines and minerals, and (10) Roads and bridges. The above ten sources account for about 2/3rd to 3/4th of the administrative component of the non-tax revenue of different States. While each State is taken up for a detailed analysis of the structure of user charges, an effort has also been made to collect information on these charges from all the States. For collecting such information, a detailed questionnaire was prepared and sent to all the States 4 . However, in the attempt to analyse a few crucial aspects of user charges, efforts were also made to collect information from a few select States. The selected States were Rajasthan (Northern Zone), Karnataka (Southern Zone), Maharashtra (Western Zone) and West Bengal (Eastern Zone). Efforts were made to collect information directly from these States by visiting the respective State capitals. The information on user charges so obtained from these States is given in Annexure A.2. Actual Revenue Realization from Select Services: In analyzing the select services, the study takes note of two time periods. The first time period is 1993-94 to 1995-96 and the second refers to the period from 2001-02 to 2003-04. 4 See Annexure A.1 for details of the questionnaire. 70 While presenting a comparative analysis, this study refers to them as the first and the second phase. The actual revenue realization of non-tax revenues as a percent of the corresponding revenue expenditure 5 was calculated from the RBI publications 6 . Table 4.1 gives RR/RE for social services and economic services across the States for the years 1993-94, 1998-99 and 2003-04. Further details for different components of social and economic services (based on data collected from the RBI) are given in Annexure A.4.1 for the same years, i.e. 1993-94, 1998-99 and 2003-04. In Table 4.1, all-States RR/RE from economic services has been higher than social services in all the three years, in spite of its decline from 21.7 percent in 1993-94 to 19.5 percent in 2003-04. On the other hand, the rate was always less than 3 percent in the case of social services for all these years, however, there was a meager increase from 2.3 percent in 1993-94 to 2.7 percent in 2003-04. Among the major States, Goa’s RR/RE from social services as well as from the economic services has been highest as compared to the other States. While RR/RE from social services in Goa increased from 7.8 percent in 1993-94 to 13.5 percent in 2003-04; in the case of economic services, it increased to an exceptionally high level of 103.2 percent in 2003-04 from the prevailing high of 81.3 percent in 1993-94 and 87.3 percent in 1998-99 (Table 4.1). In economic services, after Goa come the States of Orissa (60.1 percent), Punjab (38.7 percent), Bihar (36.6 percent) and Haryana (36.5 percent) in the year 1993-94. This order was maintained in the year 2003-04 also as shown in Table 4.1. On the other hand, with respect to RR/RE in social services, most of the States lagged far behind Goa in the year 1993-94; Punjab (4.7 percent), Haryana (4.6 percent) and Rajasthan (3.6 percent). In 1998-99, while Haryana exhibited an increase in recovery and the other two States showed a decline, in 2003-04, all these States exhibited a rise from the 1998-99 level, though these were still less as compared to the initial levels (Table 4.1). As the data available from the RBI sources are at an aggregated level, the results of the RR/RE cannot be used for policy purposes. Hence, for a detailed analysis this study uses data collected from the State Budget Documents. Making use of the data collected from State Budget Documents, Table 4.2 gives the percentage share of RR/RE of ten select components of social and economic services at a 5 Logically, one should take revenue expenditure plus annualized capital expenditure for each of the major services. However, in this study we have taken only revenue expenditure as the denominator assuming that at least this could be first met as a target for achieving the desired RR/RE. 6 RBI presents a rich source of data on State finances. Due to various reasons of comparability, however, data on revenue from non-tax sources in RBI documents are not presented in sufficient details. Hence, this study uses RBI data for only a macro analysis. 71 disaggregated level 7 . On the basis of this data, the study presents the average percentage share of RR/RE for each of the select non-tax sources for the two phases, i.e. the first three years of the study (1993-94 to 1995-96) and the last three years of the study (2001-02 to 2003-04) for the 15 major States. In the case of public works, only three States (Andhra Pradesh, Bihar and Tamil Nadu) have exhibited a rise in average RR/RE between the two phases, as shown in Table 4.2. While, in Andhra Pradesh the rate increased from 14.1 percent in the first phase to 17.3 percent in the second phase; in Bihar and Tamil Nadu it increased from 1.2 percent and 5.3 percent, respectively during the first phase, to 1.3 percent and 11.6 percent respectively, during the second phase. Maharashtra and Rajasthan are the States that have maximum RR/RE during 1993-94 to 1995-96; about 43.9 percent and 42.4 percent, respectively. However, during the second phase, this proportion declined to 19.9 percent and 35.3 percent respectively; though it was still the highest amongst all the other States. RR/RE has risen between the phases in a majority of the States in services like education, sports, arts and culture; and minor irrigation. Except for Uttar Pradesh, the average RR/RE of education, sports, art and culture was never more than 2.5 percent for both the phases. Uttar Pradesh recorded an average RR/RE of 3.4 percent during the period 2001-02 to 2003-04. In minor irrigation, on the other hand, while 11 States exhibited a rise in their average RR/RE between the phases; States like Goa, Karnataka and Tamil Nadu demonstrated quite a significant increase during the two phases: from 7.6 percent, 2.01 percent and 5.9 percent respectively, in the first phase, to 15.3 percent, 4.3 percent and 12.9 percent respectively, during the second phase (Table 4.2). RR/RE was highest in the non-ferrous mining and metallurgical industries. Among the States, it was as high as 98 times in Bihar in the first phase. However, during the same phase, it was as low as 181.0 percent in West Bengal. In the second phase it was at a maximum of 85 times in Andhra Pradesh and a minimum of 4 times in West Bengal. Apart from non-ferrous mining and metallurgical industries, many of the States have earned good revenue from forestry and wild life. In six of the States, the average percentage share of revenue receipts to revenue expenditure was more than 100 percent in the first phase; the number declined to two States during second phase. (Table 4.2). In medical, public health and family welfare, while the RR/RE was in the range of 2 percent and 10 percent; in the case of water supply and sanitation, only a few States have exhibited a significant recovery of revenue expenditure, (e.g. Goa and Rajasthan) for both the periods. In case of majority and medium irrigation, and roads and bridges, on the other hand, majority of states have seen decline in their average recovery rate between the phases. The 7 From these documents, data related to each of the sub-items of revenue and expenditure on non-tax sources for the select services (at a very disaggregated level) have been collected. Unfortunately, even in the Budget documents, some of the items such as lotteries, interests, departmental undertakings, etc. are not reflected correctly. Hence, necessary adjustments have been made, wherever required. 72 States that have witnessed a rise in RR/RE are Goa, Gujarat, Haryana, Karnataka, Orissa and Tamil Nadu for major and medium irrigation, while it was Gujarat, Haryana, Karnataka, Orissa, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu and West Bengal for roads and bridges. Thus, on the whole, the actual average RR/RE has risen only for two services in all the major 15 States: (i) education, sports, arts and culture and (ii) water supply and sanitation. This average ratio increased from 1.04 percent and 5 percent respectively, during 1993-94 to 199596; to 1.5 percent and 7.3 percent respectively, during 2001-02 to 2003-04. The average RR/RE, however, was the highest for non-ferrous mining and metallurgical industries in the ten select services, followed by forestry and wildlife (Table 4.2). Desired Percentage of RR/RE: Desired RR/RE is “the rate” which the States should aim at and make continuous efforts to attain. By estimating the desired revenue realization as a percent of revenue expenditure using the normative approach, an appraisal of the performance of the various States in collecting RR/RE could be made. Adopting a normative approach, the study presents estimated ‘norms’ of RR/RE for each of the services. The desired level of RR/RE could have been empirically derived from the historical trend. However, this differs from one place to another due to the following factors: • differences in the population density; • levels of living; • stage of development; • the socio-cultural factors; and • other region specific factors. It is necessary to fix the norms for the collection of non-tax revenues by States. Only then it is possible to judge the relative efficiency of various States in their efforts to collect non-tax revenues. The non-tax revenues of States include the earnings of public sector enterprises by way of prices for their products (fixed by regulatory authorities) or amounts recovered as user charges from a large number of public services. In fact, the State Government may be viewed as a multi-service provider. In determining the prices for the outputs of regulated firms and services provided by public enterprises, economic theory suggests marginal cost pricing or Ramsey price as the “optimal pricing rule”. User charges are price-like instruments that emerge naturally for financing of services via which its use can be restricted to only the paying consumers. Ramsey’s principle of pricing of goods and services incorporates the inverse elasticity rule and this yields Ramsey prices that are known to be efficient. These can be computed 73 separately for each of the component service or commodity 8 . The Ramsey prices thus derived are normative. However, a considerable amount of information is required to compute the Ramsey prices for each service. It requires the average long run and short run marginal costs of production of each service in each State. Given the resource constraint faced by the States, one of the objectives in such an exercise of normative price fixing is the recovery of costs. However, apart from this informational requirement, it is a known fact that the Ramsey prices do not fully cover the costs. In addition to costs that are directly attributable, a service may also be assigned a portion of the costs that cannot be clearly associated with any particular service. This kind of pricing policy may best be described as the “zero-profit fully-distributed-cost pricing rule”. To estimate the RR/RE, it is possible to use regression method by using panel data of major States for selected years. In such an exercise, the dependent variable will be the proportion of revenue receipts to the revenue expenditure. The independent variables can be population density, per capita income, proportion of relevant sectoral income in total GSDP, urbanization, literacy and availability of medical facilities etc. Our use of panel data models uses “fixed effect” types of regressions and also presumes that the desired cost recovery is net of the State specific factors. This implies that these State specific factors are either fixed for the last three years or the pattern of change has been fixed. On the other hand, factors like effects of production inefficiencies and imperfections are built into the model as random fluctuations. However, it is generally recognized that the estimated RR/RE are either approximately equal or more than the actual RR/RE. This is due to the differences that exist in the States’s perception regarding the degree of “publicness” of different services. These differences are conditioned by various socio-economic factors 9 . It is due to these differences in the socioeconomic factors across the States that there exist substantial variations in non-tax recoveries and the desired RR/RE. In the case of the services, where the desired RR/RE are higher than the actual RR/RE, scope for upward revisions exists. The difference in the actual RR/RE and the desired RR/RE indicates the inefficiencies in the recovery enforcement. In such cases, there is need to revise the rates upwardly. Given this framework of conceptual and practical limitations, this study uses the following two steps for estimating norms for desired RR/RE. First, the econometric technique for fixing norms for non-tax revenues is as follows: The econometric model for fixing norms of non-tax revenues could be described as follows: 8 Jha, Raghabendra, M.N. Murty and Satya Paul. 1999. Pricing of Postal Services in India. National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi. 9 This is illustrated by the fact that States like Rajasthan, Bihar and Orissa are rich in mineral, whereas the States of Madhya Pradesh, Chhattisgarh and Uttranchal have dense forest areas. Other States do not have an abundance of both these resources. 74 Let Yi (where i=1, 2, ..n) denote the non-tax revenue on a particular item collected by the ith State whose GSDP is Xi. Let Zi denote a vector of characteristics of the ith State which are considered important for determining the level of collection of non-tax revenues for a particular service. We fit a model having the following functional form: (1) Yi = α + β Xi + γ Zi + ui, where α, β, and γ are constants and ui is a random variable that takes only positive (non-negative) values. The above function in equation (1) can be estimated from the data for different States for each component of non-tax revenue and the fitted value, viz.: (2) Ŷi = α^ + β^ Xi + γ^ Zi can be taken as the norm for that particular component of non-tax revenue. To estimate the norms for ten select services, the following equations were set up: Equations for Regression 1 recpwd = {pcgsdp, gsdpcons} Same for both the phases 2 recedn = {pcgsdp, urban} For Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) {pcgsdp, urban, sch, tch} 3 recmed = {pcgsdp, nodoc} {pcgsdp, nodoc, beds, hosp, dis} For Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) For Phase I For Phase II 4 recwss = {pcgsdp, urban} Same for both the phases 5 recfor = {pcgsdp, gsdpfore, areaufor} For Phase I {pcgsdp, gsdpfore, areaufor, valfor} For Phase II 6 recmajir = {pcgsdp, gsdpagr, grsirrarea} Same for both the phases 7 recminirr = {pcgsdp, gsdpagr} For Phase I {pcgsdp, gsdpagr, grsirrarea} For Phase II 8 recinds = {pcgsdp,gsdpagr, gsdpindus,gsdpmfg} Same for both the phases 9 Recmin = {pcgsdp, gsdpmin} For Phase I {pcgsdp, gsdpmin, valmin} For Phase II 75 10 Recroad = {pcgsdp, gsdptran, rdl} {pcgsdp, gsdptran, rdl, nov} For Phase I For Phase II Where, recpwd = RR/RE for public works department; recedn = RR/RE for education, arts and culture; recmed = RR/RE for medical and public health; recwss = RR/RE for water and sanitation; recfor = RR/RE for forest; recmajir = RR/RE for major irrigation; recminirr = RR/RE for minor irrigation; recindus = RR/RE for industry; recmin = RR/RE for mines and minerals; and recroad = RR/RE for roads and tolls. In the above equations, for each of the ten select services, the percentage share of revenue realized to the corresponding expenditures has been calculated for the two phases (1993-94 to 1995-96, termed as phase I) and 2001-02 to 2003-04 (termed as Phase II), across the 15 major States. The average RR/RE is then obtained for each of the service for both the phases. The change in this average percentage share in the two phases indicates the efforts of the major States in mobilizing resources through non-tax sources. The details of the actual average calculations of RR/RE of each of the service are shown in Table 4.2. These regression equations give estimated RR/RE for each select service by using the average of actual percentage share of revenue receipts of a service to the corresponding revenue expenditures for the concerned service provided by the Government as the dependent variable. The independent variables are: per capita income (pcgsdp), proportion of relevant sectoral income in total Gross State Domestic Product (gsdpcons for construction, gsdpagr for agriculture, gsdpfore for forest, gsdpmin for minerals, gsdptran for transport, gsdpindus for industry), urbanization (urban), availability of educational facilities (sch for schools, tch for teachers), availability of medical facilities (nodoc for number of doctors, beds for beds in hospitals, hosp for hospitals, dis for dispensaries), area under forest (areaufor), value of forest (valfor), gross irrigated area (grsirrarea), value of minerals (valmin), road length (rdl), number of vehicles (nov) etc. Also, 15 State-wise dummy variables have been applied to get the Statewise estimated RR/RE for each service. The results of the regression using different variables and dummies have been shown in Annexure A.4.2 and A.4.3, respectively. The all-States norm is calculated by using the ‘Normative Approach’ in the above regression equations. This method, thus, estimates the ‘Norm’ for RR/RE of each of the service 76 by taking the deviation from the all-States average. The difference between the actual RR/RE for each service across the States and the desired RR/RE for each service from the all-States average gives the magnitude by which the States need to increase their existing recoveries. The results of the above regressions, fitted for all the services in the 15 major States, yield the norms for all the services. These are shown in Tables 4.3 through 4.12. The exhibits through 4.1 to 4.10 indicate the shortfall of the states actual RR/RE for a services from the desired allstates RR/RE. As the second step, the study then adopts a method of comparing the adequacy of the actual average RR/RE with the actual RR/RE of the best performing State from amongst all the States. For each of the selected service, the norm can be the State with the highest RR/RE among the major States. Thus, in the case of education, the desired RR/RE of Haryana is highest in the first phase of our study and maximum for Uttar Pradesh in the second phase (Tables 4.4). These are taken as the norm for the education in this study. The same methodology is adopted for all the ten services. The results are shown in Tables 4.3 through 4.12. The norms estimated on the basis of the related variables determine the relative efficiency of States when the State Government is viewed as a multi-service provider and the user charges as price-like instruments, which restrict the use of the service to only the “paying” consumers. Conclusions The services provided by the Government are characterized by externalities. Many of the services fall in the category of quasi-public services. Notwithstanding the characteristics of the services provided by the Government, the fact remains that most user charges for the Government services in Indian States are at an abysmally low level. Actual revenue realization as percent of revenue expenditure (RR/RE) varies according to the type of service. RR/RE for economic services have been higher than social services. Among the major States, Goa’s recovery from social services as well as from the economic services has been highest as compared to other States. At disaggregated level RR/RE has risen for only two services (education and roads and bridges) in all States. Goa has the highest percentage increase in medical followed by Tamil Nadu in public works, Bihar in education and Kerala in water supply and sanitation, Karnataka in major and medium irrigation, Tamil Nadu in minor irrigation etc. Following normative approach in calculating ‘norms’ of RR/RE and the difference between the actual and desired RR/RE for each service for all-States gives us the rate by which the States need to increase their existing recoveries. As a next step, the study adopts a method of comparing the adequacy of the actual average RR/RE with the estimated RR/RE of best practicing State. The study, therefore, makes an effort at estimating relative efficiency of States when the State Government is viewed as a multi-services provider and the user charges as price-like instruments. 77 Table 4.1 RR/RE for Social and Economic Services Social Services Major States 1993-94 1998-99 Economic Services 2003-04 1993-94 1998-99 2003-04 Andhra Pradesh 2.40 1.05 2.43 20.72 12.83 16.51 Bihar 1.30 2.05 2.40 36.61 38.09 8.38 Goa 7.75 13.19 13.45 81.22 87.28 103.21 Gujarat 3.00 1.95 2.76 18.07 12.72 33.50 Haryana 4.60 6.15 8.89 36.53 23.10 29.42 Karnataka 2.23 2.35 1.77 14.92 16.73 19.84 Kerala 2.36 1.97 2.54 19.86 9.93 10.66 Madhya Pradesh 1.92 1.22 1.53 40.83 42.03 19.83 Maharashtra 3.21 2.80 2.39 24.53 25.09 30.84 Orissa 2.90 1.54 1.74 60.08 33.60 37.90 Punjab 4.67 1.93 3.15 38.70 21.93 20.86 Rajasthan 3.57 3.22 3.54 13.14 19.96 20.27 Tamil Nadu 2.45 2.83 5.54 9.84 9.77 15.55 Uttar Pradesh 1.59 2.50 3.45 12.46 9.99 5.14 West Bengal 2.19 1.22 1.18 7.42 5.28 7.28 Major 15 States 2.55 2.29 2.96 22.26 19.25 17.64 All States 2.34 2.16 2.74 21.71 18.84 19.53 Source: RBI, “State Finances: A Study of Budgets”, Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 78 Table 4.2 Average RR/RE of Select Services States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal Major 15 States Public Works Department 1993-96 2001-04 % Change 14.10 17.34 23.03 1.22 1.25 1.73 8.49 6.35 -25.26 19.11 16.98 -11.18 8.21 7.19 -12.37 6.34 6.28 -0.89 8.19 4.16 -49.16 15.80 14.02 -11.25 43.93 19.92 -54.66 21.67 9.27 -57.21 7.68 6.64 -13.56 42.40 35.33 -16.68 5.28 11.61 119.86 11.42 4.51 -60.50 6.06 3.20 -47.25 14.37 9.65 -32.85 Education, Sports, arts and culture 1993-96 2001-04 % Change 1.54 2.49 61.49 0.15 0.84 473.38 0.58 2.11 264.27 1.11 1.61 45.62 2.30 1.84 -20.01 1.09 1.01 -8.13 2.01 2.33 15.92 0.44 0.48 8.69 0.90 0.57 -36.95 1.32 1.11 -15.67 0.79 0.83 4.98 0.51 1.26 144.31 1.44 2.20 53.10 1.40 3.38 141.33 0.45 0.58 28.51 1.04 1.51 44.62 Medical and public health 1993-96 2001-04 % Change 3.59 3.48 -3.10 2.59 3.65 41.25 4.83 6.97 44.38 8.46 5.72 -32.34 9.19 10.32 12.27 6.00 6.22 3.73 5.82 3.76 -35.45 2.26 2.48 9.60 8.69 6.31 -27.38 2.59 2.55 -1.63 8.68 6.54 -24.68 3.88 2.72 -29.88 5.86 7.15 22.11 2.24 3.05 36.30 6.53 4.04 -38.12 5.29 4.76 -9.87 Water Supply and Sanitation 1993-96 2001-04 % Change 1.92 5.32 177.55 1.33 0.26 -80.35 45.65 61.75 35.26 0.14 0.50 257.53 8.51 11.13 30.78 0.81 0.38 -53.06 0.10 1.20 1121.96 4.08 5.66 38.77 3.04 0.85 -71.98 6.71 11.23 67.21 10.31 9.58 -7.09 23.08 19.03 -17.56 1.03 3.77 265.02 0.04 0.26 615.37 0.94 1.37 45.14 5.00 7.27 45.32 Forestry and Wildlife 1993-96 2001-04 % Change 127.56 29.02 -77.25 67.07 36.78 -45.17 31.59 12.95 -59.01 25.12 28.71 14.30 29.32 28.12 -4.11 63.85 43.15 -32.42 213.99 106.58 -50.20 150.57 87.54 -41.86 72.07 35.77 -50.37 168.62 89.19 -47.10 30.46 13.90 -54.36 14.77 31.46 112.95 129.72 130.96 0.96 102.35 53.76 -47.48 50.89 30.83 -39.42 98.83 55.02 -44.33 79 Table 4.2 (Contd……) Major and Medium irrigation States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal Major 15 States 1993-96 15.04 28.68 17.24 6.07 7.17 4.85 7.09 23.46 8.37 17.74 21.21 6.83 0.28 19.49 3.51 8.67 2001-04 0.74 12.72 54.09 16.20 27.66 26.55 6.59 13.75 6.05 32.16 6.12 4.28 0.41 10.78 2.45 7.57 % Change -95.09 -55.66 213.77 166.85 285.74 446.83 -7.11 -41.39 -27.72 81.32 -71.14 -37.31 48.38 -44.66 -30.05 -12.67 Minor irrigation 1993-96 14.66 0.61 7.63 2.82 0.22 2.01 1.35 18.30 7.04 2.21 0.94 32.82 5.86 5.94 4.78 6.53 2001-04 1.26 0.79 15.32 4.97 0.36 4.26 1.88 26.55 5.47 3.15 0.26 34.29 12.92 6.03 4.02 5.91 % Change -91.42 30.48 100.84 76.13 61.02 111.77 39.88 45.06 -22.27 42.35 -72.07 4.47 120.72 1.52 -16.06 -9.53 Non-Ferrous and Metallurgical industries Industries 1993-96 0.36 2.26 1.73 15.18 4.00 17.95 1.99 12.88 2.13 6.67 0.10 3.34 0.94 14.96 18.12 7.03 2001-04 18.92 0.40 0.46 3.61 1.10 21.07 0.30 24.92 2.43 5.12 181.88 3.12 0.96 0.05 4.13 5.34 % Change 5204.29 -82.19 -73.23 -76.23 -72.55 17.36 -84.89 93.41 13.98 -23.29 191262.59 -6.53 2.14 -99.66 -77.19 -24.06 1993-96 7993.63 9873.52 3828.88 5131.86 2231.52 2095.97 322.02 9175.76 5068.65 2188.27 323.61 616.51 2661.12 2357.62 181.02 3328.31 2001-04 8532.85 1151.41 3038.33 7463.21 1254.16 2983.19 679.23 5698.55 679.31 3678.95 968.81 1733.77 6325.34 2651.92 397.37 2612.74 % Change 6.75 -88.34 -20.65 45.43 -43.80 42.33 110.93 -37.90 -86.60 68.12 199.38 181.22 137.69 12.48 119.52 -21.50 Roads and bridges % 1993-96 2001-04 Change 8.16 7.94 -2.65 6.73 4.83 -28.27 24.15 12.07 -50.03 0.88 2.61 196.33 0.12 0.64 434.84 3.57 7.34 105.49 8.36 4.76 -43.03 5.63 1.56 -72.27 58.62 0.12 -99.79 5.00 9.38 87.59 0.81 0.41 -49.28 1.81 1.94 6.87 5.60 7.12 27.18 6.18 4.03 -34.86 7.24 8.43 16.54 5.33 4.57 -14.31 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years 80 Table 4.3 Deviation from Norms for Public Works States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 14.10 -1.38 -29.83 1.22 -14.25 -42.70 8.49 -6.98 -35.43 19.11 3.64 -24.81 8.21 -7.27 -35.72 6.34 -9.14 -37.59 8.19 -7.29 -35.74 15.80 0.32 -28.13 43.93 28.45 0.00 21.67 6.19 -22.25 7.68 -7.80 -36.25 42.40 26.92 -1.53 5.28 -10.20 -38.65 11.42 -4.05 -32.50 6.06 -9.42 -37.87 15.48 43.93 1.23 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 17.34 5.98 -17.98 1.25 -10.12 -34.08 6.35 -5.02 -28.98 16.98 5.61 -18.35 7.19 -4.17 -28.14 6.28 -5.08 -29.04 4.16 -7.21 -31.17 14.02 2.66 -21.31 19.92 8.55 -15.41 9.27 -2.09 -26.06 6.64 -4.73 -28.69 35.33 23.96 0.00 11.61 0.24 -23.72 4.51 -6.85 -30.82 3.20 -8.17 -32.13 11.37 35.33 1.25 Table 4.4 Deviation from Norms for Education, Sports, Arts and Culture States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 1.54 0.47 -0.76 0.15 -0.93 -2.16 0.58 -0.49 -1.73 1.11 0.04 -1.20 2.30 1.23 0.00 1.09 0.02 -1.21 2.01 0.94 -0.29 0.44 -0.63 -1.86 0.90 -0.17 -1.40 1.32 0.25 -0.98 0.79 -0.29 -1.52 0.51 -0.56 -1.79 1.44 0.37 -0.87 1.40 0.33 -0.90 0.45 -0.62 -1.85 1.07 2.30 0.15 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 2.49 0.98 -0.89 0.84 -0.67 -2.54 2.11 0.60 -1.27 1.61 0.10 -1.77 1.84 0.33 -1.54 1.01 -0.50 -2.37 2.33 0.82 -1.05 0.48 -1.03 -2.90 0.57 -0.94 -2.81 1.11 -0.39 -2.27 0.83 -0.68 -2.55 1.26 -0.25 -2.12 2.20 0.69 -1.18 3.38 1.87 0.00 0.58 -0.93 -2.80 1.51 3.38 0.48 81 Table 4.5 Deviation from Norms for Medical and Public Health States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 3.59 -1.89 -5.60 2.59 -2.89 -6.61 4.83 -0.65 -4.36 8.46 2.98 -0.74 9.19 3.71 0.00 6.00 0.52 -3.20 5.82 0.34 -3.37 2.26 -3.22 -6.93 8.69 3.21 -0.50 2.59 -2.89 -6.60 8.68 3.20 -0.51 3.88 -1.60 -5.31 5.86 0.38 -3.33 2.24 -3.24 -6.95 6.53 1.05 -2.66 5.48 9.19 2.24 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 3.48 -1.54 -6.84 3.65 -1.36 -6.67 6.97 1.96 -3.35 5.72 0.71 -4.60 10.32 5.31 0.00 6.22 1.21 -4.10 3.76 -1.26 -6.56 2.48 -2.53 -7.84 6.31 1.30 -4.01 2.55 -2.46 -7.77 6.54 1.53 -3.78 2.72 -2.29 -7.60 7.15 2.14 -3.17 3.05 -1.96 -7.27 4.04 -0.97 -6.28 5.01 10.32 2.48 Table 4.6 Deviation from Norms for Water Supply and Sanitation States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 1.92 -5.35 -43.74 1.33 -5.94 -44.33 45.65 38.38 0.00 0.14 -7.13 -45.51 8.51 1.24 -37.14 0.81 -6.46 -44.85 0.10 -7.17 -45.56 4.08 -3.19 -41.57 3.04 -4.23 -42.61 6.71 -0.56 -38.94 10.31 3.04 -35.34 23.08 15.81 -22.58 1.03 -6.24 -44.62 0.04 -7.23 -45.62 0.94 -6.33 -44.71 7.27 45.65 0.04 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 5.32 -3.59 -56.43 0.26 -8.65 -61.49 61.75 52.84 0.00 0.50 -8.41 -61.25 11.13 2.22 -50.62 0.38 -8.54 -61.37 1.20 -7.71 -60.55 5.66 -3.25 -56.09 0.85 -8.06 -60.90 11.23 2.31 -50.52 9.58 0.67 -52.17 19.03 10.11 -42.73 3.77 -5.14 -57.98 0.26 -8.65 -61.49 1.37 -7.54 -60.38 8.91 61.75 0.26 82 Table 4.7 Deviation from Norms for Forestry and Wildlife States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 127.56 42.32 -86.43 67.07 -18.17 -146.92 31.59 -53.66 -182.41 25.12 -60.12 -188.88 29.32 -55.92 -184.67 63.85 -21.39 -150.15 213.99 128.75 0.00 150.57 65.33 -63.43 72.07 -13.17 -141.93 168.62 83.38 -45.37 30.46 -54.79 -183.54 14.77 -70.47 -199.22 129.72 44.48 -84.27 102.35 17.10 -111.65 50.89 -34.35 -163.10 85.24 213.99 14.77 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 29.02 -21.48 -101.95 36.78 -13.72 -94.19 12.95 -37.55 -118.02 28.71 -21.78 -102.26 28.12 -22.38 -102.85 43.15 -7.35 -87.82 106.58 56.08 -24.39 87.54 37.05 -43.42 35.77 -14.73 -95.20 89.19 38.70 -41.77 13.90 -36.59 -117.06 31.46 -19.03 -99.50 130.96 80.47 0.00 53.76 3.26 -77.21 30.83 -19.66 -100.13 50.49 130.96 12.95 Table 4.8 Deviation from Norms for Major and Medium Irrigation States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 15.04 2.47 -13.64 28.68 16.11 0.00 17.24 4.67 -11.44 6.07 -6.50 -22.61 7.17 -5.40 -21.51 4.85 -7.72 -23.83 7.09 -5.48 -21.59 23.46 10.88 -5.23 8.37 -4.20 -20.31 17.74 5.16 -10.95 21.21 8.64 -7.47 6.83 -5.74 -21.86 0.28 -12.29 -28.41 19.49 6.92 -9.19 3.51 -9.07 -25.18 12.57 28.68 0.28 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 0.74 -15.52 -53.35 12.72 -3.53 -41.37 54.09 37.84 0.00 16.20 -0.05 -37.89 27.66 11.41 -26.43 26.55 10.29 -27.54 6.59 -9.66 -47.50 13.75 -2.50 -40.34 6.05 -10.20 -48.04 32.16 15.91 -21.93 6.12 -10.13 -47.97 4.28 -11.97 -49.81 0.41 -15.84 -53.68 10.78 -5.47 -43.30 2.45 -13.80 -51.64 16.25 54.09 0.41 83 Table 4.9 Deviation from Norms for Minor Irrigation States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 14.66 7.49 -18.16 0.61 -6.56 -32.22 7.63 0.46 -25.20 2.82 -4.35 -30.00 0.22 -6.95 -32.60 2.01 -5.16 -30.81 1.35 -5.82 -31.48 18.30 11.13 -14.52 7.04 -0.13 -25.79 2.21 -4.96 -30.61 0.94 -6.23 -31.88 32.82 25.65 0.00 5.86 -1.32 -26.97 5.94 -1.23 -26.89 4.78 -2.39 -28.04 7.17 32.82 0.22 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 1.26 -6.96 -33.03 0.79 -7.43 -33.50 15.32 7.10 -18.97 4.97 -3.25 -29.32 0.36 -7.86 -33.93 4.26 -3.96 -30.03 1.88 -6.34 -32.41 26.55 18.33 -7.74 5.47 -2.75 -28.82 3.15 -5.07 -31.14 0.26 -7.96 -34.03 34.29 26.07 0.00 12.92 4.70 -21.37 6.03 -2.19 -28.26 4.02 -4.20 -30.27 8.22 34.29 0.26 Table 4.10 Deviation from Norms for Industries States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 0.36 -7.18 -17.76 2.26 -5.28 -15.86 1.73 -5.80 -16.39 15.18 7.64 -2.94 4.00 -3.53 -14.12 17.95 10.42 -0.17 1.99 -5.54 -16.13 12.88 5.35 -5.24 2.13 -5.40 -15.99 6.67 -0.86 -11.45 0.10 -7.44 -18.03 3.34 -4.19 -14.78 0.94 -6.59 -17.18 14.96 7.43 -3.16 18.12 10.59 0.00 7.53 18.12 0.10 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 18.92 0.50 -162.97 0.40 -18.02 -181.48 0.46 -17.95 -181.42 3.61 -14.81 -178.28 1.10 -17.32 -180.79 21.07 2.65 -160.82 0.30 -18.12 -181.58 24.92 6.50 -156.97 2.43 -15.99 -179.45 5.12 -13.30 -176.76 181.88 163.46 0.00 3.12 -15.30 -178.76 0.96 -17.46 -180.92 0.05 -18.37 -181.83 4.13 -14.29 -177.75 18.42 181.88 0.05 84 Table 4.11 Deviation from Norms for Royalties on Mines and Minerals States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 7993.63 -26.21 -1879.89 9873.52 1853.68 0.00 3828.88 -4190.96 -6044.64 5131.86 -2887.98 -4741.66 2231.52 -5788.32 -7642.00 2095.97 -5923.87 -7777.55 322.02 -7697.82 -9551.50 9175.76 1155.92 -697.76 5068.65 -2951.19 -4804.87 2188.27 -5831.57 -7685.24 323.61 -7696.23 -9549.91 616.51 -7403.33 -9257.01 2661.12 -5358.72 -7212.40 2357.62 -5662.22 -7515.90 181.02 -7838.82 -9692.50 3633.06 9873.52 181.02 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 8532.85 5362.11 0.00 1151.41 -2019.34 -7381.45 3038.33 -132.41 -5494.52 7463.21 4292.47 -1069.65 1254.16 -1916.58 -7278.69 2983.19 -187.55 -5549.67 679.23 -2491.51 -7853.62 5698.55 2527.81 -2834.30 679.31 -2491.43 -7853.54 3678.95 508.21 -4853.90 968.81 -2201.93 -7564.04 1733.77 -1436.98 -6799.09 6325.34 3154.60 -2207.51 2651.92 -518.82 -5880.93 397.37 -2773.37 -8135.48 3170.74 8532.85 397.37 Table 4.12 Deviation from Norms for Roads and Bridges States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 15 Major States Norm Maximum Minimum Phase I (1993-94 to 1995-96) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 1 2 3 8.16 -1.46 -50.47 6.73 -2.88 -51.89 24.15 14.54 -34.47 0.88 -8.73 -57.74 0.12 -9.49 -58.50 3.57 -6.04 -55.05 8.36 -1.25 -50.26 5.63 -3.98 -52.99 58.62 49.01 0.00 5.00 -4.61 -53.62 0.81 -8.80 -57.81 1.81 -7.80 -56.81 5.60 -4.02 -53.03 6.18 -3.43 -52.44 7.24 -2.38 -51.39 9.61 58.62 0.12 Phase II (2001-02 to 2003-04) Actual Deviation Deviation RR/RE from Norm from Max. 4 5 6 7.94 2.97 -4.13 4.83 -0.14 -7.24 12.07 7.10 0.00 2.61 -2.36 -9.46 0.64 -4.32 -11.42 7.34 2.37 -4.73 4.76 -0.21 -7.31 1.56 -3.41 -10.51 0.12 -4.85 -11.95 9.38 4.41 -2.69 0.41 -4.56 -11.66 1.94 -3.03 -10.13 7.12 2.15 -4.95 4.03 -0.94 -8.04 8.43 3.46 -3.63 4.97 12.07 0.12 85 Exhibit 4.1 Deviation from Norms for Public Works -8.17 -9.42 -6.85 WBL UPR -4.05 0.24 TN -10.20 23.96 RAJ -7.80 -4.73 26.92 PNB -2.09 ORS 6.19 8.55 MAH MPR -7.21 -7.29 -5.08 -9.14 -4.17 -7.27 0.32 KER KAR HAR 5.61 3.64 GUJ -10.12 -5.02 -6.98 -20.00 -15.00 GOA BIHAR -1.38 APR -14.25 -10.00 28.45 2.66 -5.00 5.98 0.00 5.00 10.00 15.00 20.00 25.00 30.00 35.00 Deviation from the Norm Phase I Phase II Exhibit 4.2 Deviation from Norms for Education, Sports, Arts and Culture -0.93 WBL -0.62 UPR 0.69 TN -0.25 -0.56 -0.68 -0.29 -0.39 -0.94 1.87 0.33 0.37 RAJ PNB ORS 0.25 MAH -0.17 MPR -1.03 -0.63 0.82 0.94 KER -0.50 KAR 0.02 0.33 HAR GUJ -0.93 -0.49 -0.67 0.60 GOA BIHAR APR -1.50 -1.00 -0.50 1.23 0.10 0.04 0.98 0.47 0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 Deviation from the Norm Phase I Phase II 86 Exhibit 4.3 Deviation from Norms for Medical and Public Health -0.97 WBL -1.96 -3.24 1.05 UPR 2.14 TN -2.29 0.38 RAJ -1.60 1.53 PNB -2.46 -2.89 3.20 ORS 1.30 MAH -2.53 3.21 MPR -3.22 -1.26 KER 0.34 1.21 KAR 0.52 5.31 HAR GUJ -1.36 BIHAR -1.54 -1.89 -3.00 2.98 1.96 -0.65 GOA -2.89 -4.00 3.71 0.71 APR -2.00 -1.00 0.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 Deviation from the Norm Phase I Phase II Exhibit 4.4 Deviation from Norms for Water Supply and Sanitation -7.54 -6.33 WBL -8.65 UPR -7.23 -5.14 TN -6.24 10.11 RAJ 15.81 0.67 3.04 2.31 PNB -8.06 ORS -0.56 MAH -4.23 -3.25 MPR -3.19 -7.71 KER -7.17 -8.54 KAR -6.46 HAR -8.41 -7.13 2.22 1.24 GUJ 52.84 GOA 38.38 -8.65 -5.94 BIHAR -3.59 APR -5.35 -20.00 -10.00 0.00 10.00 20.00 30.00 40.00 50.00 60.00 Deviation from the Norm Phase I Phase II 87 Exhibit 4.5 Deviation from Norms for Forestry and Wildlife -19.66 -34.35 WBL 3.26 UPR 17.10 80.47 TN -19.03 -70.47 -36.59 -54.79 44.48 RAJ PNB 38.70 ORS 83.38 -14.73 MAH -13.17 37.05 MPR KER 65.33 56.08 128.75 -7.35 -21.39 -22.38 -55.92 -21.78 -60.12 -53.66 -37.55 KAR HAR GUJ GOA -13.72 -18.17 BIHAR -21.48 APR -100.00 -50.00 42.32 0.00 50.00 100.00 150.00 Deviation from the Norm Phase I Phase II Exhibit 4.6 Deviation from Norms for Major and Medium Irrigation -13.80 WBL -9.07 -5.47 -15.84-12.29 -11.97 UPR 6.92 TN -5.74 -10.13 RAJ PNB 8.64 ORS -10.20 15.91 5.16 -4.20 MAH -2.50 MPR 10.88 -9.66 -5.48 KER 10.29 KAR -7.72 11.41 -5.40 HAR -6.50 -0.05 GUJ GOA -3.53 37.84 4.67 BIHAR -15.52 -20.00 APR -10.00 0.00 16.11 2.47 10.00 20.00 30.00 40.00 50.00 Deviation from the Norm Phase I Phase II 88 Exhibit 4.7 Deviation from Norms for Minor Irrigation -4.20 WBL -2.39 -2.19 -1.23 UPR 4.70 -1.32 TN 26.07 25.65 RAJ -7.96 -6.23 -5.07 -4.96 PNB ORS -2.75 MAH -0.13 18.33 MPR -6.34 -5.82 KER -3.96 -5.16 KAR -7.86 -6.95 HAR -3.25 -4.35 GUJ GOA -7.43 -6.56 -6.96 -10.00 11.13 7.10 0.46 BIHAR APR -5.00 7.49 0.00 5.00 10.00 15.00 20.00 25.00 30.00 Deviation from Norm Phase I Phase II Exhibit 4.8 Deviation from Norms for Industries -14.29 WBL -18.37 UPR 10.59 7.43 -17.46 -6.59TN -15.30 -4.19RAJ -7.44 PNB 163.46 -13.30ORS -0.86 -15.99 MAH -5.40 6.50 5.35 MPR -18.12 KER -5.54 2.65 10.42 KAR -17.32 HAR -14.81 -3.53 GUJ 7.64 -17.95 GOA -5.80 -18.02BIHAR -5.28 -7.18APR -50.00 0.50 0.00 50.00 100.00 150.00 200.00 Deviation from the Norm Phase I Phase II 89 Exhibit 4.9 Deviation from Norms for Royalties on Mines and Minerals -2773.37 -7838.82 WBL -518.82 UPR -5662.22 3154.60 TN -5358.72 -1436.98 RAJ -7403.33 -2201.93 PNB -7696.23 508.21 ORS -5831.57 -2491.43 MAH -2951.19 2527.81 MPR -2491.51 1155.92 KER -7697.82 -187.55 KAR -5923.87 -1916.58 HAR -5788.32 4292.47 GUJ -2887.98 -132.41 GOA -4190.96 -2019.34 BIHAR 1853.68 5362.11 APR -26.21 -10000.00 -8000.00 -6000.00 -4000.00 -2000.00 0.00 2000.00 4000.00 6000.00 8000.00 Deviation from the Norm Phase I Phase II Exhibit 4.10 Deviation from Norms for Roads and Bridges -2.38 WBL -0.94 -3.43 UPR -4.02 TN -3.03 -7.80 RAJ -4.56 PNB -8.80 -4.61ORS -4.85MAH 3.46 2.15 4.41 49.01 -3.41 -3.98 MPR -1.25 -0.21 KER -6.04 KAR -4.32 HAR -9.49 -2.36 GUJ -8.73 2.37 7.10 GOA 14.54 -0.14 -2.88 BIHAR -1.46 APR -20.00 -10.00 0.00 2.97 10.00 20.00 30.00 40.00 50.00 60.00 Deviation from the Norm Phase I Phase II 90 Annexure A.4.1 (a) RR/RE of Different Components of Social Services Major States Education, Sports, Art and Culture 1993 1998 2003 -94 -99 -04 Medical, Public Health and Family Welfare 1993 1998 2003 -94 -99 -04 Water Supply and Sanitation* 1998 2003 -99 -04 Housing 1993 1998 -94 -99 2003 -04 Urban Development 1993 1998 2003 -94 -99 -04 Labour and Employment 1993 19982003 -94 99 -04 Social Security and Welfare 1993 1998 2003 -94 -99 -04 Andhra Pradesh 2.06 1.01 1.53 3.75 2.27 2.00 0.52 2.58 8.08 0.74 34.32 1.70 1.14 0.78 22.64 23.66 11.31 0.88 0.51 0.54 Bihar 0.38 0.87 1.65 2.33 2.54 2.74 2.30 0.33 228.26 83.45 783.33 0.68 0.03 0.01 5.56 4.33 1.32 4.83 12.82 7.57 Goa 0.42 0.74 4.10 4.35 6.35 7.16 73.16 68.30 16.52 8.44 8.33 0.00 0.27 0.10 4.05 3.96 16.82 0.49 0.09 0.38 Gujrat 1.32 0.99 1.73 9.10 4.66 4.88 0.29 0.45 4.23 3.72 2.95 10.32 2.93 5.52 7.94 6.31 10.04 4.92 2.74 1.96 Haryana 2.62 1.56 2.13 12.72 5.96 9.16 11.49 10.56 14.17 17.33 13.10 36.13 138.24 249.83 5.01 5.39 9.16 1.38 2.98 2.84 Karnataka 1.38 0.67 0.80 5.80 4.82 3.45 1.04 0.18 12.22 6.83 22.46 1.08 1.33 0.80 12.71 13.43 15.69 0.92 14.28 1.37 Kerala Madhya Pradesh 1.90 1.80 2.66 5.41 3.95 3.33 0.57 1.19 4.04 2.99 3.26 19.22 2.01 1.41 4.09 6.37 4.61 0.29 0.04 0.61 0.40 0.43 0.39 2.42 1.37 1.60 1.83 7.95 12.77 6.23 19.70 4.98 1.11 0.87 8.16 7.66 6.09 6.77 1.89 1.80 Maharashtra 0.86 0.68 0.70 8.33 7.22 5.96 1.65 1.10 11.59 7.41 6.21 7.72 4.37 8.18 9.65 13.05 16.76 10.48 9.21 5.78 Orissa 1.60 0.84 0.64 4.50 2.03 1.65 5.58 11.43 41.34 32.89 29.69 2.32 0.15 0.04 4.51 3.58 21.10 1.33 0.18 0.44 Punjab 0.92 0.51 1.02 12.31 3.02 6.83 7.84 10.38 27.27 22.41 7.07 14.14 11.60 10.65 4.45 11.13 18.68 9.73 2.95 NC Rajasthan 0.31 0.30 2.17 4.00 1.83 1.62 21.91 18.53 5.64 5.94 7.36 1.07 0.19 0.90 4.13 4.99 6.48 1.69 1.98 1.33 Tamil Nadu 1.43 0.99 2.94 5.00 5.76 5.51 1.20 2.67 37.26 24.69 20.05 0.72 0.34 106.61 13.41 20.15 16.25 5.94 9.96 3.19 Uttar Pradesh 1.27 1.77 3.64 1.72 3.55 2.46 0.04 0.71 38.10 25.82 59.23 0.18 0.03 11.67 4.24 11.64 8.72 2.02 4.55 4.34 West Bengal Major 15 States 0.27 0.19 0.47 8.49 3.13 3.54 0.42 2.20 16.97 20.57 22.18 0.14 0.23 0.09 2.02 1.85 2.07 1.52 2.32 1.05 1.10 0.92 1.65 5.27 3.83 3.74 5.17 6.94 13.44 8.08 15.96 3.84 4.25 12.41 8.81 10.16 10.72 4.12 5.90 2.79 All States 1.02 0.86 1.58 4.77 3.53 3.38 4.78 6.18 12.52 10.07 15.10 3.33 3.44 10.01 8.46 9.58 10.02 3.70 5.42 2.64 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. * RR/RE of Water Supply and Sanitation for the year 1993-94 could not be calculated for non-availability of data. NC = Not Calculable 91 A.4.1 (b) (Contd…) (b) RR/RE of Different Components of Economic Services Crop Husbandry Major States Andhra Pradesh 1993-94 1998-99 Animal Husbandry 2003-04 1993-94 1998-99 Fisheries 2003-04 1993-94 1998-99 Forestry and Wildlife 2003-04 1993-94 1998-99 Co-operation 2003-04 1993-94 1998-99 2003-04 1.97 1.55 1.20 1.59 2.44 0.70 14.01 11.01 8.89 97.58 54.88 29.33 10.66 16.42 39.38 Bihar 1.93 2.70 2.18 1.23 0.91 0.56 43.96 38.20 38.18 109.26 22.69 43.03 17.89 3.91 8.85 Goa 11.01 10.33 8.67 7.16 18.35 8.59 8.83 12.00 8.30 35.00 30.26 10.55 16.48 11.58 8.13 Gujarat 3.08 2.53 3.04 4.11 4.07 5.77 16.98 9.30 15.48 29.06 14.38 35.55 5.05 21.70 31.61 Haryana 4.22 2.60 3.30 8.61 2.98 1.87 11.81 12.11 9.84 25.37 28.33 35.01 25.61 34.20 30.74 Karnataka 2.91 4.36 4.12 3.09 3.47 3.03 17.53 32.89 13.72 66.75 38.63 53.82 36.42 33.66 28.77 Kerala Madhya Pradesh 5.56 8.59 13.16 10.36 7.89 6.50 4.13 2.65 7.59 214.41 116.10 126.23 29.59 55.64 62.60 3.71 4.10 3.66 3.21 1.25 1.18 14.60 7.57 7.04 153.48 83.26 91.23 21.87 30.34 47.16 Maharashtra 6.32 3.74 4.28 3.71 3.86 6.00 11.72 12.68 17.47 70.82 41.37 25.73 39.83 26.83 24.09 Orissa 6.81 2.55 1.39 2.47 1.34 0.98 22.06 6.58 8.10 443.67 130.96 58.70 8.75 3.14 7.54 Punjab 14.71 7.38 10.59 9.65 2.32 2.18 97.48 32.68 20.19 75.64 15.40 8.33 18.30 12.06 6.86 Rajasthan 1.40 2.17 3.34 1.83 3.15 1.83 41.34 82.70 86.82 13.84 17.16 28.18 5.90 19.81 28.92 Tamil Nadu 9.71 7.81 15.04 5.94 5.10 6.10 6.85 4.00 30.79 132.92 78.76 98.90 17.58 25.97 7.94 Uttar Pradesh 4.75 4.20 33.39 3.26 4.76 4.78 5.77 14.39 10.50 123.24 69.84 51.52 10.80 8.97 13.70 West Bengal Major 15 States 2.43 2.46 3.49 3.43 3.67 3.11 6.74 4.99 38.71 45.27 17.28 36.41 12.06 9.02 17.92 5.84 4.94 9.48 3.96 3.40 3.30 13.52 11.41 19.53 104.48 57.29 55.00 16.03 21.96 22.33 All States 5.46 4.69 8.36 3.90 3.33 3.11 12.15 10.75 16.34 94.87 50.10 49.90 15.50 20.19 20.12 92 A.4.1 (b) (Contd…) Major States Major and Medium Irrigation projects* 1998-99 Andhra Pradesh 2003-04 Minor Irrigations* 1998-99 Power Village and Small Industries 2003-04 1993-94 1998-99 2003-04 1993-94 1998-99 2003-04 Industries 1993-94 Road Transport 1998-99 2003-04 1993-94 1998-99 2003-04 0.49 0.90 4.39 2.01 58.20 81.35 2.74 5.77 3.66 1.28 801.80 630.02 1058.63 0.00 0.00 Bihar 46.26 17.37 0.53 0.65 0.00 30.60 NC 1.30 1.43 1.51 2262.82 2443.33 301.08 0.00 9.62 0.00 0.01 Goa 3.95 43.82 2.79 29.48 105.51 114.79 140.57 1.70 4.05 10.65 2322.50 1521.52 302.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 Gujarat 10.08 94.56 1.57 7.39 0.02 0.01 3.01 1.20 0.23 5.36 2835.01 1081.55 1452.91 0.03 0.00 0.00 Haryana 23.40 48.06 1.78 1.47 0.00 0.04 0.23 6.57 14.56 45.33 252.70 218.38 387.22 523.46 230.97 387.13 3.77 18.69 3.72 4.79 87.16 10.36 1.65 19.28 14.09 8.60 63.90 206.13 922.19 0.00 0.00 0.02 15.86 7.51 0.77 2.04 NC NC 0.00 5.49 6.10 6.22 23.92 36.58 19.14 0.00 0.00 0.00 14.27 16.88 13.64 17.41 0.02 0.00 0.00 7.94 8.81 5.31 2049.53 2721.20 4581.30 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 2.26 153.12 7.87 10.64 324.64 443.65 0.38 5.92 26.63 11.71 764.81 370.16 277.05 0.00 0.02 Orissa 19.13 42.66 3.08 5.02 0.52 14.94 10.79 8.19 1.54 0.26 3338.93 1806.21 3994.79 0.00 0.00 0.00 Punjab 8.76 3.11 0.39 0.29 NC NC 0.00 15.63 8.64 4.56 190.74 29.79 1157.45 193.98 162.69 630.12 Rajasthan 4.42 6.29 27.33 30.92 0.00 0.00 0.00 10.57 6.79 1.39 249.64 315.27 872.74 0.00 2.03 0.00 Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh 2.83 2.83 3.64 18.33 NC NC 0.06 3.93 4.15 9.71 433.75 370.23 1997.41 0.00 0.00 0.00 6.98 12.18 5.64 7.56 -0.06 NC 0.00 2.63 1.71 6.49 506.36 640.27 203.14 0.05 0.31 15.31 West Bengal Major 15 States 2.09 2.81 3.14 6.75 0.04 0.04 3.33 2.20 1.16 -1.41 68.86 32.16 18.43 0.00 0.02 0.00 6.48 16.32 5.42 7.72 7.36 10.71 2.64 6.59 5.60 5.98 708.64 672.35 643.16 16.64 16.77 22.81 All States 6.47 16.86 4.92 6.58 8.62 11.60 3.92 5.95 5.09 4.85 550.13 577.18 679.33 15.51 14.74 18.39 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. * RR/RE of Major & Medium and Minor Irrigation for the year 1993-94 could not be calculated for the non-availability of data. NC = Not Calculable 93 Annexure A.4.2 Regression Results for Phase I Constant pcgsdp gsdpcons urban nodoc gsdpfore areaufor gsdpagr Public Works 37.86 -0.0015396 Education -0.47 -0.0000133 Medical 16.38 -0.0010195 Water Supply 26.28 -0.0001266 Forest Major & Medium Irrigation 45.72 -0.0020562 -9.90 0.0011747 Minor Irrigation 11.88 -0.0001781 4.52E-06 Industries 10.21 -3.59E-04 -1.71E-06 2461.28 -0.1003922 27.92 0.0004574 Mining Road & Bridges grsirrarea gsdpindus gsdpmfg gsdpmin gsdptran rdl r-square 0.000058 0.82 3.90 0.93 0.25 0.88 -144.09 0.99 0.0005355 0.0263 0.95 -0.0000136 0.00408 0.8 0.93 0.000177 -9.29E-07 0.83 0.027 0.98 -0.000085 0.0907853 0.96 Regression results for Phase II Const. pcgsdp gsdpcons urban sch tch nodoc beds hosp dis gsdpfore areaufor valfor gsdpagr grsirrarea Pwd 0.09 -0.000210 Edn 0.21 0.000101 Med 0.70 -0.000194 Wss 11.86 0.000063 -2.52 -0.000255 -38.82 0.001432 0.000019 -0.00507 0.00701 For Majir gsdpmin valmin gsdptran rdl nov R2 0.89 -11.72 0.32 0.68 0.09 -0.03 1.43 0.06 0.89 -74.87 0.99 0.000214 -0.000422 0.0000903 0.87 -82.53 0.001532 -8.22E-06 indss -30.26 -0.000975 7.63E-06 -8135.42 0.151967 5.38 -0.000122 Road gsdpmfg 0.0000107 Minirr Min gsdpindus 0.78 0.91 0.000184 -3.02E-06 0.77 0.005006 0.000206 0.81 3.59E-06 0.000792 -0.092 94 0.86 Annexure A.4.3 Regression Results for Dummy variables for Phase I Particulars Public Works APR Education Medical -11.30 -1185.86 Industries Road & Bridges GUJ HAR KAR KER MPR MAH 5.70 -10.29 -17.45 -30.32 -27.12 -21.69 -0.29 0.45 2.06 0.51 1.57 -0.19 -8.47 6.56 -22.23 -1.71 82.43 24.73 19.63 20.45 14.07 -336.22 -4.95 -865.93 -129.09 -3498.82 -20.61 15.85 Minor Irrigation Mining GOA -35.89 1.11 Water Supply Forest Major & Medium Irrigation BIHAR -28.99 -696.47 ORS PNB RAJ TN UPR WBL -12.10 -13.98 -2.38 -36.28 -39.35 -33.79 0.10 1.38 0.34 0.21 0.70 1.15 -0.03 -6.75 -9.34 -16.04 -24.56 -12.54 -21.44 -14.12 -16.38 23.56 33.72 0.19 28.05 29.51 26.68 3.88 14.66 -1174.57 -1138.79 -21.09 -393.94 -361.34 -844.37 -222.05 20.38 30.67 3.29 -3.51 11.71 13.68 19.81 17.71 19.80 3.23 0.65 1.11 0.78 17.43 -4.68 -15.52 -12.41 -13.58 -14.92 -12.20 1.22 -12.30 -12.11 -14.98 16.39 -10.11 -20.43 -13.62 -2.24 -5.28 2286.99 7657.26 3236.31 11.56 -58.00 -103.57 -191.52 0.77 -5.74 -2.17 4.10 3.01 5.68 -1.36 -4.87 -1.26 11.78 5.84 1091.58 -346.48 -1245.44 3686.68 1680.01 -2855.06 -565.66 -3493.66 156.54 -1640.36 -3584.42 -80.44 -84.97 -334.87 -78.11 -143.30 -127.32 -56.19 -96.51 -81.36 -69.88 -53.34 Regression Results for Dummy variables for Phase II APR Public Works Education BIHAR 11.30 2.54 Medical GOA 19.04 1.15 GUJ HAR 16.79 1.61 0.72 KAR KER MPR MAH ORS 11.02 2.62 0.06 10.52 0.37 2.03 2.25 1.49 8.81 5.05 0.67 15.35 14.04 16.04 9.10 11.05 PNB RAJ TN UPR WBL 8.45 29.77 4.39 -5.12 -2.69 0.59 0.53 1.01 2.74 2.60 0.76 0.45 -0.52 3.04 2.37 2.33 2.91 8.29 17.16 21.18 17.27 1.89 8.48 88.83 7.75 -25.16 110.43 13.63 -4.65 -12.13 11.30 -12.29 Water Supply 12.62 76.41 10.87 13.85 11.08 8.71 Forest Major & Medium Irrigation 21.38 28.49 30.09 23.30 -6.37 86.63 -34.45 32.26 13.98 15.16 5.80 -10.98 10.96 -46.00 41.22 Minor Irrigation 42.81 56.67 39.36 13.65 49.49 52.87 73.22 43.87 59.43 5.10 64.26 48.22 60.50 Industries 35.49 23.86 48.70 52.21 62.02 49.20 52.02 48.14 39.09 219.12 33.85 51.20 26.42 7534.22 4330.14 4552.87 4587.17 1498.22 -3320.01 147.28 4400.77 942.61 6698.62 2168.17 -830.61 3.73 -0.80 6.12 4.92 -0.54 0.48 8.58 2.23 4.74 Mining Road & Bridges 93.66 6486.75 6.68 13.19 -0.77 -42.53 95 5 Rationalising Structure of Non-tax Sources The analysis, presented in the preceding chapter, clearly highlights the fact that revenue realisation as percent of revenue expenditure (RR/RE) in most services is abysmally low as compared to the norm. Also, the RR/RE varies among services as also among States. This, to a certain extent, can be attributed to the socio-economic factors of different States, yet it requires a review of the user charges of some of the services. It is essential both for rationalising non-tax structure and for mobilizing further resources for planned development. However, while doing so it is important to keep in view the objectives of equity and efficiency. With this objective in view, this chapter presents an analysis of a few select services. Education Education is a merit good. It is heavily subsidized by the State, which is justified on the ground that it is capable of producing a wide spectrum of impact and large externalities. Also, it is considered a ‘basic human need’ and, therefore, it is presumed that the Government should make provision for this. Notwithstanding the vital role of education as an important instrument for promoting socio-economic development, in recent years, Government’s ability to continue the expansion of education has diminished due to adverse macroeconomic conditions and keen intersectoral competition for public funds. Also, the return on investment in education is affected by misallocation of resources among different types of education, inefficient use of resources within individual schools, inequality in the distribution of educational costs and benefits among various income groups. In view of this, it is generally suggested that the user charges for higher education should be raised to mobilize more resources. This is based on the belief that given the excess demand for higher education, rationalizing user charges for education through a small rise in fee would not cause a large proportion of those currently enrolled to drop out. Ultimately, it would generate additional revenues without in any way adversely affecting it. A selective approach for some specific fields in higher/secondary education may be highly profitable from the social point of view. Unless a majority of children of school going age are actually able to go through school, the expenditure on higher education can never be equitable, as those would be for privileged few who complete schooling 1 . However, how much primary education investment is required varies from State to State and depends upon the level of development of the State. Thus the decision to allocate resources should be based on social rates of return from different levels of education and requirement of the State. It is, however, important to keep in mind that increasing user charges in higher education is not based on any firm evidence to support the postulate of a significant disequalizing effect of public subsidy to higher education. If there is such an effect at all, it appears to be stronger in the developed countries than in the less developed countries 2 . Although externalities associated with basic education are higher than in case of higher education, it must be realized that higher education produces dynamic externalities, which are important for development of the societies, including specifying for rapid economic growth. It is strongly felt that essentially due to public subsidization of higher education, today higher education in India is no more elitist; it is somewhat democratized with a large proportion of socioeconomic weaker sections participating in higher education. This also helped in the creation of a large reservoir of scientific and technical personnel. The increase in the user charges for greater return to education is also not found to be proper. Private rates of return will decline if public subsidies are drastically reduced or altogether withdrawn, making investment in education unattractive from individual point of view. More importantly, it is now well noted that the social rates of return to education are not true social returns: except for tax benefits, no other social benefits are considered in the estimation of social rates of return to education. And hence it is not justifiable to argue against public subsidies in higher education. Many people now realize that higher education is no more as anti-poor as it was in the past, it is not regressive in effect, and also clearly realize that higher education is a critically important factor of economic growth, besides social mobility. It is, therefore, imperative to adopt the following policy prescriptions: First, there is a need to mobilize resources through increase in cost recovery from education. In this context, it is important to indicate that there are three levels of education, namely, primary, secondary and higher education. In India, as in other most developing countries, all types of education are heavily subsidized. A comparative analysis of the revenue realization from education (as tution fee etc.) as percent of revenue expenditure incurred on education (RR/RE) indicates that it is highest for secondary education, followed by higher education and elementary education (Table 5.1). The RR/RE in the elementary education was maximum in Haryana (2.7 percent) in the first phase followed by States of Orissa (0.9 percent), Andhra Pradesh (0.6 percent) and 1 Sundaram, K. 2006. “On Backwardness and Fair Access to Higher Education: Results from NSS 55th Round Surveys, 1999-2000”. Economic and Political Weekly, December 16-22, pp. 5173-5182. 2 Ram, Rati. 1982. “Public Subsidization of Schooling and inequality of Educational Access.” Comparative Education Review, 26 (1), February, p. 36-47. 97 Gujarat (0.4 percent). However, in the second phase though Haryana maintained its position with RR/RE of 2.3 percent, the States, which followed it were Rajasthan (1.6 percent), Gujarat (1.4 percent) and Orissa (1.01 percent). Ten out of 15 major States, on the other hand, exhibited increase in RR/RE between the phases. The above trend indicates that there is a need to rationalize the user charges in such a way that primary education is fully subsidized and the user charges are designed for secondary and higher education in such a way that these are progressive according to the income-group of the user. Second, in higher education it would be desirable to encourage greater private financing with the provision of widely available student loans and a limited number of selective scholarships. Loans enable students to finance their current studies against future income. Thus selection would not be limited to applicants with the necessary funds at the time of enrollment. This can be coupled with selective scholarships that are awarded on the basis of economic need and academic potential. Such a package provides performance incentives to all students in higher education and also helps ease the financial burden of students from poor families. Under an ideal loan scheme, students should be allowed to borrow to finance both tuition charges and their living costs. It is however, important to keep in mind that the existing system of grant of loan for education from commercial banks is not convenient for students to make use of it. The procedures call for collateral (certificate of income, documents for ownership of house or personal surety), which are difficult to comply with for resourceless students. The Government must provide the financial assistance directly through study loans/ scholarships on the basis of potential income. Finally, the involvement of private sector in providing education is welcome but the regulatory mechanism of the Government in all the aspects of education must be very strong. As in many other countries, in India too, the private sector will respond well in meeting the excess demand for public education 3 . However, the State should continue to take a major responsibility of subsidizing education. All other sources of finances, including fees, should be viewed only as peripheral ones, supplementing public expenditures. Hence, all efforts of mobilization of resources have to be made extremely cautiously, so that aspects relating to equity, efficiency and excellence in education in India are not adversely affected. Medical and Public Health Good health status of the society is vital in improving socio-economic conditions of a country, which ultimately influences economic outcomes 4 . It results in qualitative labour force and contributes to higher economic growth 5 . 3 Tan, J P. 1985. “Private Education: Some Macro Trends on Enrollment and Expenditures”. International Review of Education, 3(1),pp 103-17. 4 Bloom, D., D. Canning, and J. Sevilla, 2004. “The Effect of Health on Economic Growth: A Production Function Approach.” World Development Report 2004; 32:1-13, World Bank, Washington, D.C. 5 Barro, R., and X. Sala-i-Martin. 2004. Economic Growth. 2nd Edition, Prentice-Hall of India, New Delhi. 98 In India, health is a State subject but the Central Government has jurisdiction over infectious diseases, medical education and research, population control etc. With the given jurisdiction of the Centre and the States, the basic premise of the health policy has been to provide health care facility for every individual through the State. In the period prior to 2000, health facilities witnessed an expansion of primary health care in rural areas, and implementation of National Health Programmes (NHPs) for controlling diseases under various centrally sponsored schemes. This forced the States for increasing accountability and efficiency in resource use. The post-2000, has been witnessing shift in the health sector: the Government is encouraging the participation of private sector to address the health problems, liberalising the insurance sector to provide new avenues for health financing and redefining the role of the State from being a provider to a financer of health services as well. India has a vast and widespread public health system that has grown over time 6 . There are various departments in the Central and State Government to look into the health issues: Department of Health, Family welfare and Ayurveda, Yoga and Naturopathy, Unani, Siddha and Homeopathy (AYUSH). This has helped in increasing the public sector coverage in ensuring better health to the general public but this is not enough as though the access rate has increased; satisfaction level has declined. The structural mismatch in the institutional arrangements of these departments is resulting in negative impact on the integration of inter-health programmes. The health system in India has been decentralised to devolve the authority and power to local bodies for better governance and implementation of the NHPs. With this, the State Governments provide the local bodies the space to take decision on their revenue generation and expenditure. At the same time local bodies are responsible and accountable to the community for the service delivered. But, to what extent the Government is providing local bodies the space to operate efficiently and effectively and how far, they are successful in ensuring better facilities to general public is still a matter of question. Public health sector in India has been facing lots of problems such as inadequate revenue, lack of public investment, inadequate improved facilities, less health coverage, increase in medical cost, more exploitation of the private sector, reduction in public utilisation etc. It also lacks the availability of medication, consumables, maintenance, and repairs of buildings, medical equipments, staff motivation and consistent absentees among the doctors and other personnel. These outcomes may be attributed to low level of resource allocation for the health sector. The increase in user charge raises the cost of the utilisation capacity of the poor in the public health care; as a result, they switch over to 6 In 2001-02 there were 137,311 sub centres; 22,842 Primary Health Centres (PHCs); 3043 Community Health Centres (CHCs) and 4048 hospitals with a workforce of 345,514. See Govt. of India. 2005. “Financing and Delivery of Health Care Services in India.” Background paper for National Commission on Macro Economics and Health (August). New Delhi. Ministry of Health and Family Welfare. pp. 43-64. 99 self-medication or remain sick 7 . To overcome this if more subsidies are provided to health sector in general, this will lead to market failure and the non-poor get more benefits than the poor. Because, the rich enjoy the service more frequently than the poor and at the same time spend a higher fraction of their income on health than the poor do. Moreover there is no such accepted set of standard prevailing in the country to measure the quality of service. This is becoming the stumbling block in fixing price for a disease. If the Government does want to ensure health for all, then it has to strengthen itself to balance the demand side (the general public and the ways in which they want to access the health care) and supply side (the health system and the overall operation of the organisation). Expenditure on Public Health in India: Health being a State subject, the sector is primarily financed by the State Government, which spent their revenue on these following heads i.e. nearly 12% is allocated for drugs, medicines, supplies, and consumables; 8% for purchase of machinery and equipment, and nearly 5% for maintenance of equipment, building, electricity, rent, taxes etc., 5% on other routine expenditure and the remaining portion of the budget allocation goes to pay the salary of the employees. On the other hand the Central Government health expenditure constitutes the spending on infectious diseases, medical education, population control etc. The per capita total health spending was estimated to be around US$23 during 1997-2000, which is much less compared to the neighbouring countries 8 . Though the public sector spending accounts less than a quarter of the total health spending in India (Table 5.2), it plays a major role in terms of planning, regulating and shaping the health services delivery system. Therefore, the Government has to take note that public expenditure in the health sector can achieve the important goals like improving health outcomes, promoting nonhealth aspects of well being, and redistributing welfare among the poor 9 . User Charges- An Assessment: User charge is a contribution to cost by individual user in the form of a charge per unit of service consumed. These charges supplement the declining public budgets and therefore enhance the quality and coverage, improving efficiency and promoting equity. While it is useful to enhance user charges to have more resources for the service, this might deter access of the poor to both public and private health care, and then the goal of raising resources proves to be counter-productive as it potentially worsens health outcomes. The poor cannot afford the higher price of health care. Studies indicate that low economic status households have lower recourse to medical services and higher rates of self-medication 10 . Thus, increasing cost of care could push them not to consider themselves sick. With respect to user charge a study conducted 7 Levesque, Jean-Frederic, Slim Haddad, Delampady Narayana, and Pierre Fournier. 2006. “Outpatient Care Utilisation in Urban Kerala, India”. The London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, Oxford University Press, London. 8 World Development Report. 2003. Sustainable Development in Dynamic World. World Bank, Washington, D.C. 9 Gertler, P., and J. Hammer. 1997. “Strategies for Pricing Publicly Provide Health Services.” A Working Paper, Public Economics Division, Policy Research Department, World Bank, Washington, D.C. 10 Levesque, Jean-Frederic, et.al. 2006. op. cit. 100 in Andhra Pradesh witnessed three important aspects: first, user charge is not an independent, supplementary source of revenue; second, the aggregate utilisation of funds from user charges is low; and third, the number of poor accessing public health facilities is falling, particularly the in-patient services 11 . And this underutilisation resulted into lots of other problems. Therefore, user fee strategy has to ensure the following three areas; identification of the beneficiaries, its potential impact in providing in-patient care to the general public and utilisation of funds collected from such fees. Recognizing the fact that optimal policy to finance the health sector depends on the behaviour of consumers, private providers and civil servants, any increase in user charges must accompany rise in subsidies for poor and children to correct health care market failure and improve welfare. If the demand is less price elastic and more quality elastic, then more fees can be raised to finance quality improvement. And if the demand is more price elastic, then the Government has to allocate more subsidies as mobilisation of private sources is less. These subsidies can be shifted from low priority care to higher priority. When the Government provides subsidies to the sector in its totality, everybody tries to become free rider and thereby non-poor get the subsidies more frequently than the poor. Therefore, a policy of price discrimination should prevail that maximally improves health and redistributes subsidies towards the poor depending on its ability to identify the poor under the following four grounds, i.e. individual means testing, geographical targeting, self selection, and indicator targeting 12 . The ideal method for minimizing the revenue loss and economic resources is to identify those people who need subsidies for health services while others will be charged. But the rules and regulation to certify the poor people has to be strict and ‘at any cost non-poor cannot avail it’, should be the ideal norm. The Government has to decide the basis for measuring the poor. The price has to be charged according to the service consumed by the non-poor. Generally most of the poor live in rural areas, so it is good to locate more facilities closer to the rural area and charge zero or lower fees from them. However, facilities that serve primarily the non-poor households should have to be charged higher fees. But the difficulty is that there are some non-poor in the rural area and some poor in the urban area and thus a proper identification is required to make sure that targeted people are benefiting the most while the non-poor are paying for availing the service. The Government should introduce low subsidies for services valued and used more by the non-poor and high subsidies for services often used by the poor. Mostly these are the services for which demand is income inelastic. One specific group that may be able to afford health care is the insured population. Insurance status is a good indicator of those people who are most able to pay 11 12 Govt. of India. 2005. op. cit. pp. 268-272. Gertler, Paul J., and Jeffrey S. Hammer. 1997. op.cit. 101 simply because the insured are wealthier than the general population. By charging full cost of care to insured patients, public system can reduce subsidies to the non-poor and reallocates them to services used by the poor. The National Health Policy 2002 and the National Common Minimum Programme 2004 have emphasised to increase the public sector spending on health. However, mere increase in health spending will not commensurate perceived results in the health care system unless and until equal level of investment are made in the sector like employment and income, water, sanitation, nutrition, primary schooling and road connectivity. Finally, as in most other countries, public-private partnership in health care must be encouraged. The two sectors can complement and supplement each other. 13 . User charge may not negatively affect utilisation of service by the poor if it is accompanied by quality improvement. In fact the poor are likely to respond more strongly to quality improvement. Several studies have found that user charge is an effective way of raising revenues and since demand for health services is income inelastic will not be affected much by price increase 14 . Thus user fees have the potential of improving the efficiency in the health care system 15 . Moreover, a user fee regime with an insurance regime can beget good results but it is really a difficult and expensive task for India to implement the universal health insurance scheme. The Government can try its best to move on this desired path. Notwithstanding increase in user charges, a strong public sector would play a vital role in curbing the undesirable effects of private sector 16 . Water Supply and Sanitation Water is indispensable to human life. Every individual has a right to sufficient, physically accessible, safe, acceptable and affordable water. However, most people in the rural areas do not have access to potable water and sanitation services. In India, water supply has confronted severe scarcity syndrome and quality deterioration in recent times. On the one hand, the urban population has been rising at the rate twice the rural population growth; on the other hand, urban water accounts for 5-6 percent of the total water consumption in the country, which is grossly inadequate in 13 At present the Government is involving the private sector in achieving the public health goals in medical treatment as per pre-fixed rates; support/ancillary services (laundry, security, drug management, canteens, sanitary services, landscaping, etc) etc. See for details Govt. of India. 2005. op. cit., pp. 89-123. 14 Gupta, I., and P. Dasgupta. 2000. “Demand for Curative Health Care in Rural India: Choosing Between Private, Public and No Care.” A Discussion Paper, Institute of Economic Growth, New Delhi. 15 In fact optimal fee structure vary from country to country due to the size and performance of the public and private sector, nature of market insurance, credit and medical care and finally the administrative capacity of public sector to regulate the health sector. See Gertler, Paul J., and Jeffrey S. Hammer. 1997. op. cit. 16 Levesque, Jean-Frederic, et.al. 2006. op.cit. 102 relation to water demand. Yet, the plan outlay allocation for water supply and sanitation (WSS) has been low and decreasing substantially 17 . Pricing of Water: Issues of urban water have, in recent years, acquired increasing importance due to continuing pressures of urbanization and the limited supply of water for urban use. Most households face limited hours of service and low pressure, and 20-60 percent of water is lost in the distribution system and to unauthorized use by urban households. Many cities and towns provide water supply for one or two hours per day during normal periods and only one or two hours twice a week during lean periods. The intermittent supply and insufficient pressures keep the pipelines dry in many areas for larger durations. Low-income households and slum dwellers are the worst affected in periods of water scarcity. Given the supply constraint, the consumers tend to adjust the consumption of water up to a certain limit. But the consumption of water below a basic minimum adversely affects the health and hygiene creating environmental problems. As a result, many high-income households, industrial and business users either invest in developing their own water sources or buy water from private sources. As in most other countries, in India too, water is supplied free of charge or at a minimal price. This is based on the ground that poor households would be unable to afford these services if not subsidized. This approach to allocation of water is typically based upon the concept of meeting “basic needs”. At the same time, subsidy engenders distortions in the use of water, thereby leading to an inefficient use of resources and thus indirectly raising the costs of service provision. Subsidies can also induce inefficiency in utility operations, as utility managers face soft budget constraints. Consequent deficiencies in service provision most severely impacts vulnerable socio-economic groups, who are also the least equipped to access services through alternative means. Furthermore it fails to prevent the over-consumption of and wastage of water. Finally, it fails to recognize that high subsidization of water often benefits the middle and upper classes, rather than poor. Thus, the water supply and sanitation being merit goods, adequate public investments are required. Indian policy makers are facing a challenge of designing innovative instruments to achieve sustainable development and to enhance investment on environmental protection. But they are unable to provide the services satisfactorily. This can mainly be attributed to inefficient cost recovery; under-investment led inefficiency, increasing cost of supplying water services, subsidy, etc. Structure of Urban Water Charging: There are three types of charges for water: connection fee or fixed access charge; water tax unrelated to water use; and water rates designed as a charge on consumption. In addition there are minor charges such as meter rent, a license fee, a water cess, a meter maintenance charge where meters are provided by the water supplying agency, development charges and fixed charges for capital renovation of the water system, which are used for operating water supply systems. 17 Mathur, O.P., 2001. “Coming to Grips with Issues of Pricing Urban Water and Intra-City Bus Transport”. Discussion Paper No. 5, December, National Institute of public Finance and policy, New Delhi. 103 In India, the existing water charges are very low. The consumers pay a nominal price, which is unlinked and unrelated to financial and economic cost of water supply. The prices are fixed at the rate frequently below the marginal cost price level. This causes erosion to the revenue base for the water supply agencies to the extent that even the annual maintenance expenditure is not met, which raises serious concerns about the financial viability and sustainability of urban water utilities. This has affected the finances of State Governments, which have either absorbed the losses of water utilities by meeting a part of their recurrent expenditure or adjusted the losses by reducing the capital account support to them for capacity expansion. It is, therefore, suggested that the pricing of water should be appropriate, which will yield more revenue to be spent on improving the quality and delivery of water. The effective price should be the one that includes the water charge, surcharge and water pollution surcharge and other charges wherever applicable. The user charge based pricing of water is an important instrument of management of the water resource. However, in a country like India, with highly skewed income distribution, the uniform water pricing for all the sections of the society is not only Pareto inefficient but also would not be welfare maximizing. There is no national policy on urban water resource because of the diverse geographic, climatic and other dominant location specific factors. Even though it is a State subject, in many occasions, peculiar location specificity does not permit even the State level price policy to take care of all the variables. The individual board or municipality has the power to exercise autonomy to fix the water rates suitably. Urban water being a State subject, institutional arrangements for its pricing vary across States. At one level, price structures distinguish metered connections from unmetered supplies as also bulk provision from non-bulk provision. At another level, price discrimination is common with (a) categories of water users which comprise not only the principal categories of domestic users and non-domestic users but also assorted categories consisting of water use for washing motor vehicles, passages and stalls, cattle sheds, stables, and the like, and (b) income group of households, assumption being that low-income households use less quantities of water and high income households have higher consumption levels. Water pricing also differs with the quality of water supplies, e.g. filtered, unfiltered, tube-well supplies and the like. Furthermore, several types of water tariff are used in this sector. A price differential exists between industry and domestic consumers. The industries are charged with economic prices where as domestic water supply is highly subsidized. Thus, there is a need to have lesser rate categories which are transparent in nature for the ease of management as different rates which are uniquely and unilaterally fixed by individual water agencies complicate the generalisability of the system. It is believed that an effective management of the water boards has potential to enhance own resources up to an extent as high as one third of the total revenue. The enhanced recovery at the margin would improve the viability of the municipal water 104 services to a great extent. The failure of the existing tariff structure to provide sufficient incentives for economizing water use has necessitated the need for rationalization of prices. Among the other things, accurate measurement of water on a volumetric basis is an important requisite for an effective pricing policy. Therefore all water connections must be metered for the success of the full cost recovery. A perfect metering system also helps in conservation strategy to benefit the society in the long run. The existence of nonmetered water connections as well as non-functioning water meters is an obstacle to efficient planning for water resource. Non-functioning meters offer a payoff to the household, as these are usually charged on the basis of an arbitrarily fixed flat monthly charge. Sanitation Compared with water supply, the sewerage service has a distinctly larger externality and hence the case for Government intervention in the management of wastewater (WW) and sewerage needs adequate emphasis. About 80 percent of the water used enters into the WW stream. Urban India is by and large, deficient in infrastructure to provide adequate treatment facilities for huge quantities of WW and sewage. In absence of adequate treatment facilities WW and sewage are disposed of in the creeks or into rivers and the sea directly. As a result there is deterioration in the quality of water in natural water bodies. In the context of the deteriorating urban environmental quality and the need for augmenting the resources of municipal bodies, there is a case for rationalizing user charges by linking the charges to the quantity of WW generated. To correct market failure, a policy of charging economic price from the urban non-poor and an affordable price from the urban poor (second best pricing) is desired and would be efficient. There is an urgent need for reforms in the water delivery system. Following measures can be taken into account to bring about the relevant changes in management of the water: 1. The first relates to the relevance and effectiveness of the existing pricing systems and structures. As shown earlier, the pricing structures of urban water are in several parts, which are differentiated according to the nature or users, quality, quantity, and several other factors. Apart from complex structures these pricing structures are obsolete, and need to be replaced with structures that are simple, easy to apply, and transparent. 2. Cost recovery requires the technical and administrative ability to operate an effective pricing system. If the system is to be based upon the User-Pays principle, then a reasonably accurate metering system must be installed and maintained for those direct water users, and a timely billing and collection system has to be in place. Most importantly, there has to be a mechanism to enforce payment of accounts within a reasonable period of time. For cost recovery purposes, the prices should cover the replacement cost of the supply, including capital, operation, maintenance and 105 administration. This is the difference between the concern of a utility to remain financially viable and the economic efficiency concerns of the Government. The increasing block-rate tariff structure may be adopted where the water requirements for meeting basic needs are made available at a low price while higher amounts are charged at the full costs of supply. Also, if price of industrial use were based on the full costs, it would encourage conservation and recycling of water. 3. The third issue is linked to the unbalanced revenue base of water utilities, with much of the burden currently being borne by the non-domestic sector. The finance data of urban water utilities has clearly brought out the extent of cross-subsidies that exists in the water sector. It has two adverse impacts: (a) the non-domestic users, mainly industry and commerce, pass on the costs associated with higher tariff to domestic users in the form of higher prices of their products; (b) lower prices for households mean larger wastage of water. It is imperative for water utilities to move towards a more rational pricing structure which may yield a positive net benefit as the non-domestic users may be expected to pass on the cost savings associated with lower water prices in the form of lower output prices. Also, the provision of drinking water has a strong element of a public good mostly in terms of public health; it often makes sense to subsidize lifeline consumption for those who might otherwise be unable to afford it. The subsidies would need to be well targeted and phased out over an agreed period. With a view to improving resource use efficiency and sustainability of the environmental quality the following specific reforms could be useful: To increase the accountability of institutions to improve the reliability of service; having private sector participation; to improve financial sustainability of the service; to create financial incentives to reduce O&M, capital and financing costs; to improve the environmental sustainability of service; and to have participation of the community groups. Therefore, using above suggested ways can satisfy the motto of efficient economic instruments for sustainable resource use with improved level of services for basic needs. Forest and Wildlife Forests are an important natural resource and play a key role in the development of a country providing ample amount of economic and non-economic benefits to the human kind through various goods like timber, fuel wood, fodder, and other non-timber food products. They are a source of natural habitat for bio-diversity, repository of genetic wealth and opportunity for eco-tourism and help in watershed development such as regulating water, conserving soil, controlling floods, and contributing to the process of carbon sequestration 18 . They are a treasure house of energy, environment, tourism, industries, employment opportunities, other miscellaneous things, and above all revenue generators of the States. 18 Mathur, S. Archana, and Arvinder S. Sachdeva. 2003. “Towards an Economic Approach to Sustainable Forest Development.” Working Paper No. 2/2003-PC, Planning Commission, Govt. of India, New Delhi, p. 2. 106 The management of forests falls under the Concurrent List of the Constitution, which provides the States to earn revenues within the ambit of National Forest Policy. Forests account around 67 million hectares, i.e. nearly 20.64% of the total land area in India. In addition to that another 3.04% is under tree cover. Thus around 23.68% of area is under forest and tree cover and of the total forest 61.7% are categorised as dense forest. Table 5.3 provides the information about the forest coverage of the various States in India. Madhya Pradesh accounts for the maximum forest cover; Arunachal Pradesh is having 2.5% of country’s geographical area but contributing 10.1% of the total forest cover of India. While Rajasthan, Punjab, Haryana, Bihar, Uttar Pradesh and Gujarat put together account 8.2% of the total forest area of India while covering 29.4% of the geographical area. Madhya Pradesh, Chhattishgarh and Arunachal Pradesh accounts for nearly 1/3rd of dense forest in the country. Expenditure on forest relates to the cost incurred in its cultivation, maintenance, restoration, depreciation, and other miscellaneous costs to obtain the timber, non-timber forest products, eco-tourism and other benefits 19 . Also there are direct as well as indirect costs involved to keep the wildlife in the various protected areas. The input cost for plantation, extraction cost, market expanses for forestry products and direct expenditure on afforestation. Apart from these direct costs, there are certain indirect costs like infrastructure cost for promoting eco-tourism, markets for timber and non-timber forest products etc. Most of these investment and expenditure in forests is undertaken by public agencies. The expenditure on forest is minimal of total plan outlay of the State Governments. As the States are running out of fund, they have been seeking assistance from the Central Government to bear their forest expenditure. The financial support of the Central Government to the forest and wild life is less than 1% of the total budget of the five year plan. It was around 4% of the GDP in 2002-03 20 , most of which relates to afforestation and eco-development, forest and wild life, national river conservation, and environment. However, the total available funds are not enough to conserve and protect the forest and wild life in India. To ensure a sustainable forest management it is required that the Central Government should make efforts to increase its investment in forest having long gestation period. The major sources of forest revenue are timber and fuel wood, besides these there are bamboo, sandal wood and oil, ringal, katha, resin, thatching grass, gum, honey, wax, hides and horns, cane, tendu and kendu leaves, medicinal herbs, fodder grass, boulder, bazri, stones, lime and lime stones etc. Timber and fuel wood provides inputs to various industries such as; ply wood, match box, sports goods, pencil, packing case, agricultural 19 Mathur, S. Archana, and Arvinder S. Sachdeva. 2003. “Towards an Economic Approach to Sustainable Forest Development.” A Working Paper No. 2/2003-PC, Planning Commission, Govt. of India, New Delhi, pp. 6-7. 20 Government of India. 2006. Report of the National Forest Commission. Ministry of Environment and Forests, New Delhi, Chapter-21. 107 equipments, manufacturing industries, and railway etc 21 . Forest also raise revenue from tourism through the biosphere reserves, sanctuaries, national parks and zoos and revenue from fines and forfeitures, receipts for compensatory plantations and other items 22 . However, there are supply side problems of low productivity occurring due to reduction in forest area (development activity, encroachment), technological gap, overextraction, over-grazing, fire, inadequate implementation of management prescription etc. that need to be tackled 23 . It is felt, that the community based joint forest management could enhance the revenue of the States if these difficulties like bureaucratic permits, legal support to sell certain species and complete information about the markets, channels and prices will be regulated. Wild life Conservation India has about 89451varieties of animals comprising 7.28% of the total animals in the world and reported to have 16500-19400 varieties of plants, around 7% of the world 24 . To protect the wild animals and plants the Government resorted to vast areas of forest in the form of biosphere reserve, national parks and zoos, sanctuaries etc. Currently, there are 597 national parks and sanctuaries encompassing 154572 sq km or 4.74% of the country’s total geographic area. The Wildlife Protection Act 1972 is a positive policy framework for the conservation of the endangered species within a protected area. The purpose of the biosphere reserve is to conserve all forms of life, along with its support system, in its totality, so that it could serve as referral system for monitoring and evaluating changes in natural eco system. In this respect the Supreme Court has banned the removal of dead or fallen trees from the protected area of forests but extraction of bamboo and other non-timber forest produce is permissible from deciduous forest. Forest and wild life are listed in the concurrent list vis-à-vis the Central Government deal with the policy and State Governments implement those policies. Wild life wing of Government of India has 3 divisions, i.e. (i) Project tiger division (ii) Project elephant division (iii) Wildlife division. The authorities of these divisions are looking after the administration and control. Government of India provides a part of financial support to the States through certain centrally sponsored schemes (scheme for national park, sanctuaries, project tiger, project elephant, eco-development, tribal development); others are borne by the States. Though the Central assistance is increasing in absolute terms but in relative terms it is hovering around below 1% of the plan periods. Therefore, the total outlay of both the Governments are not sufficient to keep the endangered species within these protected areas. 21 Joshi, A., and P.N. Pande. 1991. “Forest Policy and its Impact on the Rural Population in Uttar Pradesh Hills.” A working Paper, Giri Institute of Development Studies, Lucknow, Chapter-III. 22 Govt. of Karnataka. 2003. First Report of Revenue Reforms Commission. Finance Department, Bangalore, pp. 221-272. 23 Govt. of India. 2006. Report of the National Forest Commission. Ministry of Environment and Forests, New Delhi, Chapter-3, 6 & 7. 24 ibid. Chapter-9. 108 The Supreme Court of India have passed an interim order in 2001 restraining the Government of India from regularisation of encroachments and issued directives in prohibiting the diversion of any protected area. Obviously this has given some relief to the endangered species. Subsequently the Wildlife Protection Act, 1972 amended in 2003 with 2 new category of protected area; conservation reserves, community reserves to provide more space to the wildlife. Pricing of forestry Benefits: Forest revenues are mainly realised from forests on Government lands and forest produces are directly being exploited and sold by the State Government. The benefits of the forest can be categorised as direct and indirect, but so far only direct benefits are being priced and indirect benefits are ignored 25 . As the scope of this study is on mobilizing non-tax revenues of the States through user charges, only direct benefits are looked into. The main sources of forest revenue through user charges are (i) Sale of timber and firewood (ii) Sale of seedlings (iii) Grazing fee (iv) Fine on head loaders (v) Issue of permit / licenses (vi) Penalty / compounding etc26 . But so far only marketed products are being charged from the stakeholders leaving the non-market benefits of forests 27 . Not only this, there are significant lacunas in pricing the forest produce. Studies undertaken to develop methods for valuing non-market benefits indicate various methods of valuation, as shown in Table 5.4. It is suggested that the technique of Multi Criteria Analysis (MCA) - a mathematical programming technique to measure specific benefits of the forests, could be used to raise the user charges for the direct beneficiaries as the cost of benefit is rising 28 . The need of the hour is to make a paradigm shift in raising revenue of the forest. This problem can be catapulted if an earmarked fund is allocated to maintain the forest for a longer period of time. For this reason some States have raised the issue of compensation for maintenance of forest cover to the Central Government. Also, the experiment of Joint Forest Management, as attempted in many of the States could be rewarding. Irrigation Irrigation projects are in the nature of publicly supplied intermediate inputs, for socio-economic, engineering and institutional reasons, even though they are not pure 25 A study conducted by Madhu Verma (2000) to examine the contribution of forests of Himachal Pradesh derived the indirect benefits far exceed the direct benefits of the forest, i.e. Rs53000 per hectare and Rs21000 per hectare respectively. 26 Govt. of Karnataka. 2003. Opcit. 27 In 2002-03 forests contributed Rs27013 crore to India’s GDP at the current price which was 1.2% of the GDP in that year. The contribution of forest varied from1.0% to 1.5% from 1993-94 to 2002-03.A study by IGIDR (1999) on Forest Resources Accounts of Maharashtra estimated that the direct benefits of forest contribute around 2.9% of the net domestic produce of the country. 28 The experience of Karnataka shows that revenue realised through user charges is Rs100 crore per annum at present, however a rough estimate indicates the possibility of increasing the revenue to more than Rs1500 crore. 109 public goods. Setting up irrigation projects in the public sector confers substantial economic benefits on private users. There are also significant externalities (positive or negative), as a consequence of which the State plays a major role in the sector Water Rates - The Present Scenario: All the States charge for the use of irrigation water from public sources, except in Assam and the North-eastern States which do not levy irrigation rates. These charges are in the form of water rates, levied on area actually irrigated, differentiated by season and crops. The crop-wise rates, in general, are highest for perennial cash crops and lowest for irrigated dry seasonals. Also, the rates vary according to season, with the rates for hot weather seasonals being considerably higher than during the monsoon season. In many States, the rates are further differentiated by categories of irrigation projects to allow for differences in the quality of irrigation as reflected in the quantum, duration, and assurance of water supplies. For example, Haryana has classified its canal system into three broad groups for the purpose of rate determination. Rajasthan charges different rates for irrigation works, constructed before and after 1952. Besides water rates, a few States levy general or special purpose cesses on irrigated areas/crops (Annexure A.2). Also, lift irrigation from public sources Government canal or public tube wells - are invariably engaged at higher rate than for surface irrigation. In the case of tube-wells, changes being on the basis of hours of watering rather than area appointment to volumetric pricing. Basis for Existing Rates: The water rates are fixed by the Central Water Commission (CWC) that takes certain considerations into account while determining these rates 29 . The considerations include quantum of water consumed, paying capacity of irrigations, assurance of supplies and need to cover annual costs incurred in providing irrigation. However, there is no uniformity or consistency of practice among the States in this. Consider, for example, the relation between rates and water requirements. It has been observed that crops consuming more water irrigation also pay more per hectare. However, the rate per unit volume of water consumed varies greatly across crops. In no State does the gross receipt by way of water charges per hectare account for more than 3 percent of the gross productivity per hec. of irrigated area. This and the wide variability in the level and structure of rates per hec suggest that there is scope of rationalization of the rate structure. Reasons for low recovery: Revenue generation from the irrigation projects, however, has not kept pace with the creation of potential. Revision of water rates has been infrequent, hesitant and very much less than the increase in costs. The all-round deterioration in the financial performance of irrigation projects is stark and nearly universal. The total unrecovered costs on account of major and minor irrigation works has increased magnificently over the years. This resulted in a huge financial crisis for the 29 Government of India. 1992. Report of the Committee on Pricing of Irrigation Water. Planning Commission, GOI. New Delhi. 110 Government. Thus there is an urgent need of a serious and detailed scrutiny of the accounting of the costs and revenue of minor irrigation works to determine the order of subsidies involved. Cost recovery in irrigation has been a major problem in rural and agricultural water use in India. Important reasons include poor water delivery management by irrigation department, poor State of maintenance of irrigation works, in accuracy of published technical data on these works and allegedly widespread corruption in irrigation departments. Among the other underlying causes, huge and soaring ‘subsidies’, mostly in the form of unrecovered costs of goods and services provided by the public sector, is the main reason for financial crisis confronting the Central and the State Governments 30 . This resulted in a loss of irrigation potential in some completed irrigation projects. Moreover, though, unrecovered costs are essentially subsidies, but one must not assume that the entire subsidy accrues to users of irrigation. Part of it represent the costs of inefficiency in producing and distributing irrigation services on account of defective design, inordinate delays in completing projects, over-extended distributary systems, waste, and other factors which inflate capital costs; and overmanning, relatively high administrative costs, avoidably high costs of repair works and other factors which raise operating costs, and/or affect the efficacy of assessment and collection of revenue. It is not possible to determine how much of the implicit subsidy is attributable to inefficiency and how much really benefits farmers because of the under-pricing of water. The other main reason for revenue deterioration is that raising water rates is seen as invitation to electoral disaster to the political parties and thus few Governments, irrespective of party affiliation, are willing to take risk. Revision of water rates has been infrequent, hesitant and very much less than the increase in costs. The rates increase were themselves rather modest and no State has accepted, very few implemented the Irrigation Commission recommendations by reviewing and adjusting rates every 5 years. The experience has also shown that neither rates are raised nor the enforcement of the prescribed rates is strict. There is ample scope in the existing arrangements for collusion between officials and farmers leading to under statement of area irrigated, especially of area under crops carrying higher rates. Laxity in assessment is compounded by laxity in collection which resulted in phenomenal increase in losses on account of irrigation. Moreover, the capital cost of irrigation projects has risen over the years because of three factors: general inflation; new projects being in more difficult locations; and higher costs of borrowing. According to CWC estimates between 1976-77 and 1993-94 there was a four-fold increase in construction costs due to increases in prices of material and labor. Adjusting for inflation, the average investment per hectare of addition to irrigation potential rose by two and a half to thrice times. All these factors, among other, resulted in inadequacy of funds for working expenses (operation and maintenance costs) which invariable cited as the reason for deterioration of systems and the quality of services the Government offer. 30 Vaidyanathan, A. Irrigation Subsidies. Madras Institute of development studies, Chennai. 111 Policy Implications: Irrigation is one of the key inputs for crop production in as much as the productivity impact of better seeds, fertilizers arid other input is critically dependent on the way water is used. It is, therefore, both legitimate and necessary to address the pricing of this input as one of the first steps and an integral component in the process of rationalizing the totality of the price structure and raising the efficiency of water. Efficient water use: The upward revision of water rates does not necessarily mean increase in cost of production as more efficient water-use reduces the quantum of water per unit area without affecting output per unit area and which may lead to reduction in the real burden of water charges. Hence, keeping the prices of inputs much below their cost and unrelated to their consumption leads to inefficient water-use. Towards Full Cost Recovery: Irrigation, especially, major and minor irrigation absorbs a large amount of resources mobilized at high cost by the Government. The benefits, however, accrue only to a limited area and population. In such a situation, the possibility of extending the benefits of irrigation to new and wider areas will be severely constrained if people who are already benefiting from public investments do not bear the costs of the services that they receive. Any policy that may result in greater potential benefit for large number of farmers can surely be expected to be politically more acceptable than the continuance of the present system of heavily subsidizing the service to a relatively small number of beneficiaries. A revision in the level and structure of water rates is thus, necessary in the interest of both efficiency and equity. Need to Improve Quality of Services: At present the management of canal system are unable to accept any obligation regarding the quality of water supply or to make sure that systems are constructed and managed as economically as possible for a given standard of service; sizeable segments of the command do not get any water at all or get much less water than their crops need; the supplies tend to be quite unreliable in terms of quantum and timing; there is hardly any cost consciousness. Typically systems are over capitalized; huge time and cost over-runs are allowed to pass without much scrutiny; over-manning and relatively high overheads inflate operational costs. These problems are compounded by the adoption different cropping pattern by the farmers from those assumed at the time of project formulations. The users of public irrigation will be willing to pay much more for water, provided they are assured of a better quality of services (covering quantity, duration and schedule of water supply) and the rate are linked to this. It is far too simplistic to view the problem as merely one of revising the level and structure of water rates to cover O&M and part or all of the capital costs. Revision of water rates should go hand in hand with measures to improve the quality of service and to keep a check on costs. Pricing for Domestic and Industrial Use: A part of irrigation water is used for domestic purposes and industrial uses (including thermal power stations). However, in so far as non-irrigation uses are not charged the full cost of providing water and total revenues from irrigation projects are expected to cover overall costs, the rates charged for 112 irrigation will be higher than they should be. This inequity will be aggravated if the volume consumed by domestic and industrial uses increases rapidly. In light of such an agreement, the rates for non-agricultural uses should be revised so that the costs are fully recovered and arrangements built into the supply contracts for ensuring full and prompt recovery of dues. Avoiding Complexities: At present water rates are almost everywhere fixed cropwise and with reference to area irrigated. Under this system, it is essential to record and verify whether or not each individual plot comprising the command received irrigation and for what crop and in which season. The assessment and collection of charges from individual farmer is based on this record. The number of plots to be checked and the number of farmers with whom the Department has to deal being enormous, such a system is very expensive and inherently difficult, to manage. Moreover, area irrigated is a poor indicator of the services provided by irrigation systems as the water requirements of crops vary on account of differences in (a) duration (b) cultivation seasons; and (c) needs for non-consumptive users. These differences are not systematically or adequately taken into account while fixing rates per unit of irrigated area under different crops. Further, the productivity impact of irrigation varies greatly depending both on what crops are grown and on how much irrigation is available, in what quantities and when. All this argues strongly for a system, which makes water charges explicitly a function of the volume and season. Under such a system, the amount farmers have to pay gets linked to the quantities of water used by them and the quality of service. This will put pressure on managers of the system to rationalize water allocation procedures and make sure that they provide the designated volume of water according to a specified schedule. Making rates a function of predictability of supplies (in respect of quantum, frequency and season) also takes care of the productivity aspect to a substantial extent; and it obviates the need for elaborate records of area irrigated by crop. Royalty on Mines and Minerals Minerals are vital ingredients in shaping the socio-economic development of States that are rich in these resources 31 . In the past, the mineral sector in India was completely under the public sector. Even now, approximately 80% of the total value of minerals originates from it. However, with the opening up of the economy and reforms in various sectors, efforts are on to have more and more private sector participation in the mineral sector. Management of mineral resources is the responsibility of the Central and State Governments as per Entry 54 of the Union List, and Entry 23 and 50 in that of the State. Mineral resources are, therefore, regulated by the Mines and Minerals (Regulation and Development) Act, 1957. According to this Act, the major minerals are under the Central 31 Important minerals include coal, iron ore, bauxite, mica, manganese, gypsum, chromite, copper, dolomite, barytes, gypsum, graphite, ilmenite, lead and zinc, kaolin, limestone, limited reserve of gold and diamond. 113 Government and minor minerals are under the State Governments. The details of the Constitutional provisions relating to mines and minerals are given in Annexure A.3. The National Mineral Policy recognizes the fact that mines and minerals are nonrenewable sources of energy and a valuable natural resource. The Policy ensures that there is optimal exploration of reserves, the maximising of mineral rents, compliance to environmental standards, incentives for reinvestment of mineral rents and to the displaced community. Mining and Mineral Sector in India: The Present Scenario: India produces as many as 84 minerals comprising 4 fuels, 11 metallic, 49 non-metallic and 20 minor minerals. The aggregate value of mineral production in India was around Rs 696 billion in 2003-04, contributed by more than 3123 mines. Fuel minerals contribute around 80%, metallic minerals 8%, non-metallic minerals 3% and minor minerals 9%. The contribution of the public sector was around 80%. About 85% of the reporting mines are concentrated in 10 States, viz. Madhya Pradesh, Chattishgarh, Rajasthan, Gujarat, Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, Jharkhand, Orissa, Tamil Nadu and Karnataka. Non-tax Structure in Indian Mines and Mineral Sector: In addition to taxes 32 being levied on mines and mineral sector in India, non-tax levy of royalty and other cesses are levied to maintain the sustainability of the resources for the future generations. Royalty and dead rent on major minerals are governed and fixed by the Central Government, and for minor minerals by the State Governments. The yield of both (major and minor) minerals accrues to the States. The rates of royalty vary according to the type of minerals (Annexure A.2). Also, there are miscellaneous non-tax imposts on various activities of mining such as pre-extraction, extraction, semi-processing, marketing and transportation. However, most of these are levied at the first two stages of the mining activity. The details of these imposts are given below: Reconnaissance permit fee is levied at the time of demarcation of an area as a possible mine, and when the mine lease is sanctioned. The applicant has to submit the application with a non-refundable fee, at the rate specified by the respective State along with a refundable security for the observance of terms and conditions for mining of the permitted area. Prospecting and mining lease fee is paid by the bidder under a prospecting license. The holder of the prospecting license is required to pay in advance an annual prospecting fee at a rate fixed by the State Government on a per hectare basis. The payment is independent of the mineral extraction activity. If a quantum of the mineral is removed at the prospecting stage itself for commercial purposes, then royalty has to be 32 There are various types of taxes on mineral activity and these are levied by the three layers of Government i.e. Central, State and local. The taxes are corporate income tax, union excise duties, custom duties and Central sales tax imposed by the Central Government, stamp duties, registration fees, road tax and VAT imposed by the State Governments, property tax, octroi / entry tax, and various rural taxes levied by the local Government. 114 paid at the specified rate for the removed amount. After successful prospecting, the lessee applies for grant of mining lease by paying a fee specified thereof. If the extraction has not commenced and the mine is lying untapped, dead rent has to be paid by the holder of the mining lease for the area of mining lease granted to him. This is fixed by the Central Government like royalty and revised every three years but it is collected by the State Government. Dead rent is a deterrent against the tendency of the lessee to corner leases and keep them idle to prevent competitors from accessing mineral bearing areas. It is paid before actual production and varies according to the lease period and area brought under the lease. When the lessee becomes eligible to pay royalty, he pays either of the two, whichever is higher. A mineral lessee is also required to pay a surface rent in respect of the area used by the lessee for the mining operation. This rent is fixed at a rate not exceeding the land revenue specified by the State Government. It is levied on the basis of area assessed as non-agricultural area and used for mining activities. The holder of the mining lease pays a royalty in respect of any mineral removed or consumed from the leased area. In India, royalty for minerals is charged on a quantity basis (specific-rated) or on a sale price basis (ad valorem). The royalty rate for the major minerals is revised every three years by the Central Government. Currently, royalty of most of the minerals are levied on an ad valorem basis and only a few are assessed on quantity basis (Annexure A.4). Apart from royalty, the State Governments levy some cesses (having different names) on major minerals. Cess is a kind of levy charged for meeting some specified expenditure like welfare, education, health, construction of roads etc. It is levied either on the royalty payable or the quantity of mineral production. Royalty linked cesses were struck down by the Supreme Court of India except for the State of West Bengal in 1992. There are also several other specific levies which are imposed by the State Governments, e.g. State water pollution consent fee, State air pollution consent fee, local area welfare development charge, environment and forest charge, safety zone charge for mining operation and so on. All these levies and their rates vary from State to State. Revision of royalty needs to be viewed along with the movement of prices, production, and productivity. Royalty is an important source of non-tax revenue to the mineral producing States. The potential to increase revenue through royalty is quite significant. However, the present level of this source of non-tax revenue is very low. The grading of minerals, rates of royalty, periodicity of revision of royalty rate, basis of royalty, and the type of royalty all influence the level of revenue accruing to a mineral producing State. If the rates of royalty remain unchanged for a long time, the real value of royalty declines significantly due to rising inflation and the States lose considerably. Finally, as recommended by Anwarul Hoda Committee, the royalty rates should be based on the value base of the mined minerals rather than on tonnage system. 115 Roads and Bridges Road system is an important component of infrastructure. Development of roads in India is under the jurisdiction of both the Center and the States; the Centre is responsible for the construction, operation and maintenance of the national highways and scheduled roads, and the States for all the other roads. Presently, the length of the national highways is 58,000 kms, and State highways is 1,36,000 kms. Together they constitute less than 10% of the total road network (3.5 million km), and account for over 75% of the total road based traffic. After Independence, Indian planners gave more importance to railways than roads resulting in the slow expansion of the road network in India. Over the years, road transport has emerged as a dominant mode of transport, but the funding as well as provision of services has been insufficient. In 1985, the Government initiated the private-public partnership (PPP) to finance, build and operate toll roads of their choice. The offer was under the BOT (Build, Operate and Transfer) approach, which did encourage the private sector to mobilize resources to set up toll roads. At the State level, some States have been trying to promote private sector participation on a BOT basis. Financing of India’s road network: The Government of India’s expenditure on road is 12% of capital expenditure and 3% of total expenditure; still road maintenance is grossly under-funded, which has resulted in low standard of roads. In India, roads are treated as a public good. Roads are financed mainly from general revenues with little support from user charges, fuel cesses, tolls, substantial private sector funding, market borrowings and external assistance. The gap between the total inflow and projected outflow is met from market borrowings where the Ministry of Finance guarantees the borrowings. Borrowings can be raised by assigning the toll revenues of National Highway Authority of India (NHAI) and if necessary, the toll account can be placed in an escrow account. A borrowing limit has to be fixed whereby the debt service obligation will not exceed 50% of the projected annual cess revenue. The interest on market borrowings has been calculated at the rate of 9% per annum. Additional budgetary support is restricted to the North East Region, some specific region defined by the Government of India or any additional project undertaken during the eleventh plan. The sole objective of the creation of NHAI was to commercialise the highway projects. The Road User Non-tax Charge in India: At present, toll revenue and cess on fuel are the two major source of non-tax revenue in India. Revenue from cess: - A special cess of Rs1.50 per litre on High Speed Diesel and Motor Spirit has been applied under the Act of Central Road Fund, 2001. Some States, like Uttar Pradesh, levy an additional tax on transport fuel sales. This type of cess supports the development/maintenance of national and State highways as well as the development of rural roads. The growth rate has been assumed to be 3% per annum. There was a provision for earmarking of a cess that could be used to bridge the gap of BOT (Tolls) and the surplus realized could be used in construction contracts, annuity 116 repayments, land acquisition etc. It must be pointed that the entire cess (up to 2029-30) is assigned for debt service. Toll revenue: - This is one of the major non-tax sources of revenue for the States (Table 5.5). States like Gujarat, West Bengal, Rajasthan, Orissa, Kerala, and Tamil Nadu are showing an increasing trend in toll revenue during the same time period. However, few States are declining in toll revenue collection, e.g. Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra and Uttar Pradesh. These major States are putting their focus on other sources of non-tax revenue. Tolls have a tremendous potential to increase the revenue raising capacity of roads and bridges of the States. However, the toll collection needs sufficient up-gradation and mechanisation to collect more revenue. All future phases of NHs and State highways are on the basis of Public-PrivatePartnership (PPP) or Construction Contract (CC). There are three forms of PPP- BOT (Toll) system, BOT (Annuity) system, Special Purpose Vehicle (SPV) system. Under the BOT (Toll) system the concessionaire undertakes construction and maintenance of the road during the concession period at the expiry of which assets are transferred to the Government. The budgetary support of Government can not exceed 40% of the cost of each project. Private funding is sustained by revenue from a specified toll structure for which they get the tolling right for that concession period. Award for BOT (Toll) are made through competitive biddings on the basis of minimum grant or the shortest concession period. The system of BOT (Annuity) has the provision of concession, which includes building the road and having its maintenance for a fixed period. But there is no upfront tolling right. It is NHAI’s annuity payments over the concession period that makes private funding financially viable. Award of the project is made through competitive bidding in respect of minimum annuity payments. NHAI fixes the concession period uniformly for 15 years. The SPV is a joint venture company set up by two or more promoters to execute some projects. It is generally used for toll road projects and is partly funded by user entities. Finance is funded by insurance companies, pension funds and other institutions having long term funds at their disposal. With the Government keen on private sector participation in the roads sector, a new Model Concession Agreement (MCA) has been finalised to streamline publicprivate-partnership (PPP) projects in the State highways sector. Many States requested the Government to evolve an MCA for State highways, as in case of NHs, to sustain investor interest in the up-gradation and maintenance of State highways on BOT basis. To improve the toll collection, it is recommended that the Government should start a system of electronic toll collection either through microwave technology or through infrared technology. This will be able to solve the problem of congestion due to toll collection. Microwave technology, which is commonly used throughout the world, is based on radio frequency waves which will provide information to the toll collection plaza about the vehicle. Infrared, used mostly in remote controls, is relatively a new technology for toll collection. By using this technology, the processing of toll collection can be completed within a fraction of a second. 117 Table 5.1: RR/RE from Elementary, Secondary and Higher Education in Major States RR/RE from Elementary Education RR/RE from Secondary Education 1993-96 2001-04 % Change 1993-96 2001-04 % Change Andhra Pradesh 0.60 0.57 -6.11 3.39 2.26 -33.21 Bihar 0.00 0.10 NC 0.08 0.10 27.57 Goa 0.01 0.04 512.23 0.02 0.59 2856.12 Gujarat 0.39 1.36 247.20 0.64 0.74 15.24 Haryana 2.68 2.31 -13.91 2.55 0.82 -67.70 Karnataka 0.05 0.40 752.54 2.47 1.96 -20.89 Kerala 0.06 0.08 24.06 4.09 3.63 -11.37 Madhya Pradesh 0.02 0.01 -55.74 0.12 0.27 129.65 Maharashtra 0.24 0.27 11.47 0.11 0.07 -39.96 Orissa 0.91 1.07 17.94 0.04 0.14 258.12 Punjab 0.22 0.47 116.81 0.97 0.52 -46.77 Rajasthan 0.34 1.56 355.30 0.64 0.59 -8.22 Tamil Nadu 0.00 0.21 6877.37 2.78 3.50 25.88 Uttar Pradesh 0.12 0.01 -91.78 3.74 2.88 -23.03 West Bengal 0.01 0.01 127.87 0.03 0.02 -36.20 15 Major States 0.25 0.48 92.94 1.54 1.25 -18.95 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note: NC = Not calculated States RR/RE from University and Higher Education 1993-96 2001-04 % Change 0.58 0.47 -18.80 0.00 4.01 NC 0.69 8.36 1114.50 4.06 2.30 -43.30 0.95 0.42 -55.74 0.34 0.00 -100.00 2.73 3.05 11.89 0.83 0.87 4.54 0.47 0.24 -48.19 0.58 0.35 -39.97 0.89 1.45 62.09 0.75 0.60 -20.33 1.80 1.70 -5.34 1.11 0.00 -99.97 0.21 0.09 -56.35 1.03 1.04 1.24 118 Table 5.2: Household, Public and Total Health Expenditure in India (2004-05) (Rs. Crores) States Household Govt. Other Total HE as% of Exp. Exp. Exp. Health THE Exp. PE as% of THE OE as% of THE Central Govt. 0 14819 730 15549 0 95.3 4.7 Andhra Pradesh 6441 1696 640 8777 73.38 19.39 7.29 Bihar 11854 1091 202 13147 90.17 8.3 1.53 Goa 524 116 22 662 79.17 17.48 3.35 Gujarat 4893 996 424 6313 77.51 15.78 6.71 Haryana 3385 421 175 3981 85.03 10.56 4.4 Karnataka 3847 1267 353 5467 70.36 23.18 6.46 Kerala 8373 1048 281 9702 86.3 10.8 2.9 Madhya Pradesh 6432 1051 228 7711 83.41 13.63 2.96 Maharashtra 11703 3527 726 15957 73.34 22.1 4.55 Orissa 2999 684 111 3795 79.04 18.02 2.93 Punjab 3493 827 273 4593 76.05 18 5.95 Rajasthan 3399 1190 267 4855 70 24.5 5.5 Tamil Nadu 3624 1590 760 5974 60.67 26.61 12.72 Uttar Pradesh 17158 2650 550 20359 84.28 13.02 2.7 West Bengal 7782 1715 433 9929 78.38 17.27 4.36 All States 109308 17965 5906 133178 Grand Totals 109308 32784 6636 148727 73.5 22 4.46 (GOI+States) Source: - National Health Accounts (NHA) (2001-02) Notes: (i) Household expenditure based on NHA for the year 2001-02 and extrapolated for 2004-05. (ii) Central Govt. expenditure includes transfer to states, other central ministries and central PSUs; and data obtained from demand for grants (provisional), Govt. of India. (iii) Govt. expenditure includes Central, States, Local Govts and PSUs; data obtained from state finances (provisional), RBI, various issues. (iv) Other includes foreign agencies, private firms and NGOs; data relates to 2001-02 which is subsequently extrapolated for 2004-05. (v) HE as% of THE- Household Expenditure as % of Total Health Expenditure; PE as% of THE- Public expenditure as % of Total Health Expenditure; OE as% of THE- Other Expenditure as % of Total Health Expenditure. 119 Table 5.3: Forest Cover in Different States in India (Sq. K.M.) States: Geographical Area Actual Forest Cover 2003-04 Total Forest Area 275069 44419 63821 Bihar 94163 5558 6473 Goa 3702 2156 1224 Gujarat 196022 14946 19113 Haryana 44212 1517 1558 191791 36449 43084 Andhra Pradesh Karnataka 38863 15577 11268 Madhya Pradesh 308245 76429 95221 Maharashtra 307713 46865 61939 Orissa 155707 48366 58136 Punjab 50362 1580 3084 Rajasthan 342239 15826 32488 Tamil Nadu 130058 22643 22877 Uttar Pradesh 240928 14118 16826 West Bengal 88752 12343 11879 Kerala Source: - State of Forest Report 2003, Forest Survey of India. 120 Table 5.4: Methods for Valuing Forest Benefits 121 Table 5.5: Toll Collection of Major States (Rs. ‘000) States Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 103708 151136 134881 372864 263060 130493 79105 4148 3579 658 7600 121463 74699 8472 2762 966 11816 188223 0 10368 8680 3193 15674 206226 4241 98 13473 2213 18665 35548 410 307 16655 399 22369 29353 99 76 246982 0 18955 30242 7407 8198 11778 2580 152931 3947 1336 7361 10199 1153 158242 17524 57201 9296 13013 167 149022 21777 1233 5979 21847 136 91904 80497 849 5884 25850 0 59028 97275 301 19112 52734 3727 24774 118623 Source: Comptroller and Auditor General of India, Finance Accounts, Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 122 6 Procedural Reforms for Non-tax Revenue and Issues in Delivery of Services The analysis, presented in the preceding chapter, clearly highlights the fact that it is the Government that has to mobilize resources through the increase in user charges of the goods and services provided by it. However, the delivery of services by the Government, especially in the areas of education, water supply, power, sanitation, and health services etc, face enormous pressures owing to the fact that the capability of the public sector has not kept pace with the services demanded by its citizens. There is a growing awareness that the ability of existing institutions to deliver the quality of services is deteriorating. It is, therefore, extremely important that the procedures for the delivery of some of the services, viz. education, health and infrastructure etc, that have a direct interaction with the society are improved considerably. These should be designed in a suitable way for use by the masses. This will make the delivery of services effective and adequate 1 . Complexities in Procedures in Delivery of Services There is a wide gap between the efforts made by the Government in providing services and citizen “satisfaction” from the quality and reliability of services. For example, a nationwide survey done on the quality of the public distribution system (PDS) revealed that while 72 percent of households used the PDS, less than 10 percent were fully satisfied with the quantity, quality, or fairness of the system 2 . In a ranking of the quality of service delivery across 15 major States, the States of Assam, Bihar, Orissa, Rajasthan, and West Bengal were 1 World Development Report. 2004. “Public Sector Underpinnings of Service Reform”. In Making Services Work for Poor People. The World Bank, Washington, DC. 2 Paul, S., S. Balakrishna, K. Gopakumar, S. Sekhar, and M. Vivekananda. 2004. “State of India’s Public Services: Benchmarks for the States”. Economic and Political Weekly, February 28, pp. 90-34. placed in the lowest tier. Likewise, in most of the services provided by the Government, it is often the targeted group (the poor people) who do not get access to them in requisite quantity and quality. While many of the services provided by the Government contribute to improving human welfare and quality of life, this chapter focuses on services that bring people into direct contact with the Government (having interaction with the officials) for delivery of the service. These include education services, health services and infrastructure services such as water supply and sanitation services. Education Education is a medium through which the people come to know their socio-cultural background that helps them to identify themselves with their own country. It develops human resources for different levels of economic activity and helps them to undertake the necessary research and development needed to attain the perceived national goals. Investment in education, therefore, is significant to regulate the present and the future. In spite of the significance of this service, even after almost sixty years of Independence, India still is in need of a tangible mechanism in the educational system to transcend its 35 percent of illiterate population. Though many reforms have taken place over the years, the “three R’s” of Amartya Sen, (i.e. Reasons, Reachness and Range) have not yet been fully achieved. The delivery of service of education faces a variety of problems. These are mentioned below: Unaffordable Access: Most of the poor people, especially the rural poor, are not yet able to have access to school facility simply because they can not afford its opportunity cost in terms of money that the poor children have to forgo while studying in the school instead of helping their parents in the field or doing other manual work. Although universal literacy is the heart of Government education policy, despite repeated rhetorical commitments to universal enrollment, even the modest goal of universal primary school completion has not been realized. This is mainly because of the limited reach of the service to the targeted population. The children still have to walk a long way even to reach the nearest primary school, as sometimes there is no clear-cut short route to the school. In addition, there still exist social stigmas, e.g. the caste system that prevents the lower caste children’s entry into the village school. Dysfunctional Schools and Low Quality of education: Completion of schooling and the learning process falls short of expectations because the providers (school or college) are dysfunctional. While most of the teachers try conscientiously to do their jobs, some of them remain absent or do not attend to their work carefully 3 . Low capability, weak motivation, the 3 PROBE Team in association with Centre for Development Economics. 1999. Public Report on Basic Education in India. Oxford University Press, New Delhi; Aruna R. 1999. “Learn Thoroughly: Primary Schooling in Tamil Nadu”. Economic and Political Weekly, May 1, pp. 1011-1014; EPW Research Foundation. 1994. ‘Social 124 lack of complementary inputs and an ineffective regulatory mechanism makes the quality of teaching abysmally low. This makes the future prospects of learning outcomes very dismal. Low Client Responsiveness: When communities are not involved in establishing, supporting, or overseeing a school, the school is often seen as an entity to which they cannot relate. People often complain of absent teachers and the demand for illegal fees to get their children into school or to influence the examination results 4 . Villagers refer to the school as “the Government’s school” and not as “our school”. As poor people are not aware of their rights and cannot voice their opinion, they have no expectations from the Government schools and prefer shouldering the burden themselves 5 . They become the victim of the chauvinist attitude of the educated mass and the so-called policymakers. Medical and Public Health The public health sector in India has been facing lots of problems such as inadequate facilities, less health coverage, and an increase in medical cost 6 . Although India has a Constitutional commitment to universal provision of health care, the ratio of Government health expenditure to total expenditure on health is only 21 percent - half the public spending ratio of the developed/ “free market” countries such as the United States (45 percent) or Chile (44 percent). If one takes expenditure as a measure, India has one of the most “privatized” health systems in the world - of the 195 countries listed in the World Health Report 2005, only five had a ratio of public to private spending lower than India. Although the public health delivery system consists of a large number of dispensaries, primary health care institutions, small hospitals providing specialist services, large hospitals providing tertiary care, medical colleges, paramedical training institutions, laboratories etc., there has been a clear absence of any deliberate strategy to use specialized organizational tools for achieving public health goals. Recently a survey 7 was conducted to track the public facilities in Rajasthan continuously for a year. It was found that despite huge investments in expanding the access to public health care, the use of these public health facilities is low for all Indicators of Development for India – II: Inter-State Disparities”. Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. XXIX, No. 21, May 21, (Special Statistics – 8); Dreze, J. and A. Sen. 1995. India: Economic Development and Social Opportunity. Oxford University press; Kumar, R., S. Santra, A. Mukherjee, T. Banerjee, and M. Kundu. 2005. “Public-Private Interface in Primary Education: A Case Study in West Bengal”. Economic and Political Weekly, April 9, pp. 1550-1555; Mehrotra, S. (et. al.) 1998. “Reallocating Public Spending for Basic Social Services in Developing Countries”. Economic and Political Weekly, July 4, pp. 1717-1724. 4 Narayan, Deepa, and Patti Pettesch. 2002. From Many Lands: Voices of Poor. World Bank, Oxford University Press, Washington, DC. 5 Daramola, A G, Hawa A Biu, Ogoh Alubo, Agi S P I Shebu, Uchenne M Nzewi, and Paul Francis. 1998. Hard Lessons: Primary Schools, Community, and Social Capital in Nigeria. World Bank, Washington, DC. 6 Purohit, Brijesh C. 2004. “Inter-State Disparities in Health Care and Financial Burden on the Poor in India”. Journal of Health and Social Policy, Vol. 18 (3), pp. 37-60, Howarth Press, USA; Purohit, Brijesh C. 1997. "Structural Adjustment and Health Care Sector in India: Some Policy Issues in Financing". QEH Working Paper No.2 (on Internet), April, University of Oxford. 7 Banerjee, A., E. Duflo, and A. Deaton. 2004. “Health Care Delivery in Rural Rajasthan”. Economic and Political Weekly, February 28, pp. 944-950. 125 income groups. It was observed that the poor relied on traditional healers and made rare visits to these facilities. However, there are several reasons for the poor quality of delivery of health services in India. The three main factors are – (i) poor governance and dysfunctional role of the state; (ii) unrealistic goal setting and lack of a strategic vision; and (iii) weak management. Poor governance and dysfunctional role of the State: No system, however well designed it may be, can function without a guiding, regulatory force and a strong ‘politicalwill’. Comprising of both the political and administrative class, this ‘combined’ control mechanism is needed to effectively translate policy aspirations into actions. Further, unlike the other services, governance of health is difficult as it is intertwined with socioeconomic and cultural factors. As a result of this, health personnel have little control over final outcomes. This is made more complex by various ministries administering to matters that directly affect population health without any coordinating mechanism in place. The health system comes under three categories-- primary, secondary and tertiary. These are administered and monitored by different bodies, none of which work in co-ordination with the other. As a result of this, there has been dilution in the concept of health care, where curative services are supposed to imply continuum of preventive and promotive health care. Such a fragmentation has negative effects that make the integration of health services problematic. Also, it weakens the technical capacity to think holistically and results in the duplication of scarce resource use. Inadequate Goal-setting: Weak evidence base for strategic vision: The absence of good quality research for evidence-based policy formulation is one of the reasons for the poor goalsetting and program designing in health. Neither the Ministry at the Centre nor at the State level has adequate in-house capability to design research studies, collate data and analyze research findings of the various health programmes to enable evidence-based policy-making. Hardly any importance is given to the collection and review of health data nor to its analysis for future reference. Substantial resources are being spent on programmes and interventions that have a poor evidence base. For example, there is no evidence to indicate the current burden of malaria, or maternal mortality. Similarly, hardly any studies are available to assess the efficacy of the use of a drug or its treatment protocol under different settings and conditions. This is crucial for formulating differential medical strategies to suit the diverse conditions prevailing in India. In eight of the States, substantial investments were mobilized from the World Bank to upgrade, strengthen and establish hospitals at the district, sub-district and block levels. However, while the projects undertaken were successful in improving the quality of health care in urban and semi-urban areas, the “expected” outcomes, (e.g. increase in institutional deliveries) were not realized. Had the focus been on establishing the referral system and linking the other disease control measures with the Reproductive and Child Health (RCH) projects, investments made for strengthening the health systems would have had a measurable impact on reducing maternal, neonatal and infant deaths. This experience clearly demonstrates that mere increase in investments in infrastructure does not automatically translate into better public health outcomes. It also underscores the urgent need for conceptual clarity on the 126 expectations of the organizational structures that have been established and the urgent need for standardization of facilities across the country. While it is clear that infrastructure development had little linkage to goal setting, it is also seen that policy intervention per se often lacked focus. These were not based on hard evidence, and had weak institutional capacity to translate policy into action. Management Failures: There are various factors that are responsible for the failure of health management systems in India, viz. low budgets; untimely and irregular supplies; and corrupt practices. The dispersed and disaggregated administrative responsibilities, plus the conflicting job profiles, make accountability a difficult proposition. All these factors have serious implications for the quality of management and efficiency. A majority of doctors opt for specialization and/or urban practice. Their reluctance to serve in rural areas has become a major impediment in the Government’s ability to provide health services to the rural population. The desire for an increase in earnings and fear of career stagnation compels many of the doctors to opt for a private practice. As a result, the absenteeism of doctors and frontline workers from their place of work is very high. Various studies conducted by Indian experts 8 , including those by the World Bank 9 , indicate that absenteeism among doctors working in primary health centres ranges from 40 to 50 percent. The recruitment policy is a contributory factor for the lack of motivation among doctors to provide services in rural areas as very often, postgraduate students are recruited by the Governments and placed at PHCs where the skills acquired by them during post graduation are of little relevance. Vehicles without POL 10 budgets, beds without washing allowances, X-ray machines lying idle for the want of consumables or maintenance budgets, delay in delivery of drugs etc. also contribute to management failure. In addition, the quality of service delivery is also perceived to be low due to the unfriendly, rude, corrupt behaviour of the personnel working in these facilities, distance, inconvenient timings, and lack of reliability in the availability or the skill of the provider etc. also reflect management failure. The most demotivating factor is the lack of appropriate facilities and required inputs. These are crucial to motivate a qualified doctor to do his best for his patient and derive job satisfaction. The working condition for nurses and/or midwives is worse due to inadequate and unreliable supply of inputs; absence of supervision and technical guidance; and the limited opportunities for career advancement. There exist many corrupt practices within the health system, e.g. prevalence of unauthorized private practice, the issuing of fake medical certificates, transfers, posting, recruitment, ‘tolerating’ absenteeism etc. It is these, which make the health system ineffective. 8 Mohan P., S. Iyengar, S.B. Mohan, K. Sen. 2003. “Daily Up-Down”. Why Should an Auxiliary Nurse-Mid-wife (ANM) of Rajasthan Prefer to Reside Within Her Work-Area? Udaipur: Action Research and Training for Health; Rangarao, A.P. 2003. Report on Role and Efficiency of ANM and Male Worker in Primary Health Care. Andhra Pradesh: A Qualitative Study funded by DFID. (Unpublished paper commissioned by DIFD, New Delhi, India). 9 World Bank. 2004. State Health System Development Projects II. Implementation Completion Report, World Bank; Washington, USA, September. 10 POL indicates petroleum, oil and lubricant. 127 Water Supply and Sanitation The daily supply of piped water in urban areas is much lower in India than in other developing countries. Moreover, the availability of water has been declining and people deal with this problem in a variety of ways. At many places the true total costs of coping with the “inadequate” water supply is often found to be much higher than the monthly water bill (as people invest assets or time in coping with the irregular water supply). Full-pressure, i.e. “24/7” water supply remains a pipe dream in many cities. Moreover, the limited number of the network of water access points has to be widely shared, which increases the waiting time and very often, this simply overwhelms the system. Poor people bear a disproportionate share of the impact of inefficient water and sanitation services. Very few of the poor are connected to a network. When they do have access, the installation has to be shared with many more people. The prices they pay are among the highest, generally more than those paid by the more affluent households who have water pipe connections. The inefficient price differential results in inequitable practice of subsidizing piped water, lack of scale economies for independent providers, or what is even worse, the providers taking advantage of the poor people’s lack of choice. In general, the standards of maintenance of the water supply and sanitation facilities are poor. Very little of the expenditure goes for maintenance and hardly any for replacement. The poor maintenance of the system results in cost escalation and shortens the life of the system causing high failures rates. Thus, the major difficulties that the public and water management bodies facing today are the following: • Increasing scarcity of water resources (often of bad quality) requiring water resource management; • Increasing water demand (especially in the urban centres) which requires more water to be produced, distribution systems to be developed, and also water demand management; • Increasing demand for a better service (water quality, water quantity, pressure) and thus, an improved operation and management of the water system, in contrast with the preparedness of the existing systems which are in need of rehabilitation; • Scarcity of traditional financing sources in the context of the general increase in construction and operation costs. Owing to lack of treatment facilities, a great proportion of untreated waste and sewage water flows into open drains. Heavily loaded with pollutants, this wastewater and sewage water enters the water distribution system. This occurs especially during the monsoon season, giving rise to many water-borne diseases such as cholera, gastro-enteritis and dysentery. These 128 diseases take a heavy toll of human lives and give rise to severe health hazards 11 . Existing control measures, regulation and fiscal instruments have failed to contain the deteriorating water utility services and pollution abatement in the urban areas. Rationalisation of Procedures in Delivery of Services as Fiscal Measure When one observes failure in services provision, it is very easy to point a finger at the frontline provider for the inefficient delivery of services. The proximate causes of this failure can be categorized into the following four categories12 : lack of knowledge, lack of capability, lack of assets or inputs, or lack of motivation. However, a focus on the proximate causes of failure in delivery of a particular service can lead to a counterproductive tendency to put the “blame” for the failure on the individual provider, rather than identify the systemic issues that trap even the best and highly capable people within dysfunctional systems. No system creates good services by attacking or undermining the frontline providers of those services. Thus, the enforcment of good management and governance is absolutely essential in these sectors. Corrupt practices in these sectors hurt persons who are poor and cannot afford the alternative means of dealing with the problem. No market can function or sustain itself unless there is a minimal level of integrity, fair play and rule of law. Thus, the time is ripe to review the existing arrangements keeping in view the long-term perspective. Policymakers and observers of contemporary India acknowledge that strengthening service delivery in India requires not just new schemes or better logistics or managerial fixes but radical reforms in institutional arrangements. It is the politicians and policymakers who can make reforms happen. However, reforming institutions is a long-term process. It requires the initiation of a sequence of reform measures that will ultimately bring about radical institutional reforms in the long run. The challenge India faces is to identify the weakest link in the chain of accountability. This is the starting point to develop initiatives that will ultimately contribute to the larger reform agenda for institutional change. The basic services like education, water supply and sanitation, and health system need to achieve greater efficiency in some of the aspects given below: Regulation and enforcement: The primary role of a Government should be to protect people’s welfare. This is done by instituting regulations and rigorously monitoring their enforcement. The objective of regulations must be to increase awareness and create a sense of accountability among providers regarding the quality of service delivered. This should not be a routine application of a standard or a rule. Thus, supervision needs to be supportive and not perspective or fault-finding, as the objective is not to drive away the providers but to persuade them to adhere to quality and safety of the service. This calls for regulations related to 11 Purohit, Brijesh C. and T. Siddiqui. 2004. “Environmental Determinants of Disease and Mortality Pattern in India: A Factor Analytic Approach.” In Chugan P.K and M. Mallikarjun (Eds.), Managing Trade,Technology and Environment , , New Delhi: Excel Books, 12 World Development Report. 2004. Opcit.. 129 intensive training programmes and performance monitoring system. Supportive supervision is a new skill that needs to be nurtured in the Government sector 13 . Thus, in the health sector, the key challenge to governance is the enforcement of regulations related to the “quack” or the unqualified practitioner in the villages. Good governance would require a political will to resolutely enforce discipline and make the public health system work, besides educating the people on the rational use of medical practices or drug use. Also, given the wide variations across the States, it is necessary to undertake a comprehensive assessment of the adequacy of the existing laws, identify the gaps and come up with a package to improve the service delivery to the targeted people. On the other hand, what successful education systems share is a working structure of accountability: clear objectives, adequate resources, and capable and motivated providers. Clarifying objectives and the role to be played by policymakers and providers is the first step towards good governance. Devolution of authority: Decentralization has to be viewed in the context of devolving authority and power to the States by the Centre, to the districts by the States and from the districts to the multi-layered local bodies. But success depends on how responsibly and with how much accountability the task is performed. If decentralization just replaces the functions of the Central ministry with a slightly lower tier of Government, while everything else remains the same, viz. the relationship between the people and the government; and between the government and the providers, there is little reason to expect a positive change. However, a clear-cut delineation of duties and functions to be carried out by the local bodies at different levels vis-à-vis the Government departmental hierarchies; the financial implications of those functions and systems for utilization and reporting; and the kind of authority, powers, or control these local bodies have on the functionaries (responsible for discharging those duties) will help in the early realization of the goals for which the services are being provided. For example, in education the operation of schools is highly centralized which restricts the functioning of the community-run and private schools. It also discourages them from making their contribution to development of education. On the other hand, easing these controls mobilizes additional private and local resources for education without excessively increasing the Government’s fiscal burden. Greater decentralization, including giving more leeway for private and community schools, would also improve efficiency within the schools by encouraging greater competition amongst them. It would also develop managerial accountability within the schools as the system would be more organized. Stimulating Competition in and for the Market of Services: In India, the Government has the virtual exclusive monopoly, which does not provide services to many - especially the 13 Mills, A., R. Brugha, K. Hanson, and B. McPake. 2002. “Approaches for Improving Delivery in the Non-State Sector: What Is the Evidence on what works, where and why? ” Paper presented at the Making service Works for the Poor Conference. Eynsham Hall, Oxfordshire. November 4; Purohit Brijesh C. 2001. “Structural Adjustment, Private Initiatives and Policy Options: A Case of the Indian Healthcare Sector”, Health Policy and Planning, 16(1), January-March, 87-97, Oxford University Press, U.K., Purohit Brijesh C. 1996. “New Directions for Public Health Financing” Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. XXXI (8), Feb. 24: pp. 450-453. 130 poor - and provides poor quality services to those who do have access. The situation in India remains one in which the public monopolies face no competition either ‘in the market”, or “for the market”. However, given the global revolution sweeping today’s world, competition does matter in the provision of public services. This would have the following implications: 1. It would require a clear contract between the bulk provider and the nongovernmental provider which would define the rights and responsibilities of both parties 14 . 2. It would require a clear contract between the provider and those who receive services. The absence of such contracts is one of the major reasons why the monopoly-providers remain unaccountable to users, and information remains so poor and opaque. 3. It would require that costs are “revealed”, and the distinction between legitimate costs and those costs (such as massive over-staffing), which should not be passed on to the users. The entry of private and other non-governmental providers would naturally lead to comparisons between the costs and quality of services provided by different providers. This will put pressure on public providers to improve their performance. The States need to surrender those tasks, which they need not perform to others. On the other hand, the State needs to develop the capacity to do many things, which only the State can do 15 . Use of IT for Better Decision-Making: Effective leadership rests on access to organized information, which is increasingly becoming possible due to e-governance. This information (about inputs and outcomes, and achievement of targets and goals) is necessary for formulation of policies and monitoring activities. This may be related to technology, human resources, or infrastructure. The use of IT cannot be over-stated as it is fundamental to curbing errant behaviour. IT should be used for record maintenance, monitoring supply and inventory control, tracking events and disseminating information to consumers. This would place vast power in the hands of the Government to guide, monitor and correct the system Such data analysis also reduces subjectivism in transfer policies and personnel development, and ensures transparency in all transactions. This is the only check to abuse of discretionary power. On the other hand, despite being one of the world’s IT centers, India has been slow and uneven in adapting to this change in the information environment. Also, there has been a severe decrease in the data collected owing to political and institutional instability, economic 14 Such a contract exists between the Delhi Jal Board and the private operator of the Sonia Vihar water treatment plant in Delhi. Delhi Jal Board is responsible for ensuring the bulk water supply for the plant. It has to pay a fine of Rs. 50,000 a day if bulk supply is not provided. This has led to the DJB making unusually energetic efforts to ensure provision of bulk water supply for the plant and coincidentally, for the people to be served. 15 World Bank. 2005. “An Invigorated Indian Water State for the 21st Century”. In India’s Water Economy: Bracing for a Turbulent Future. Document of the World Bank. Report No. 34750-IN. 131 problems, budget constraints and lack of professional education etc 16 . As in the case of health, technology has a role to play even in patient care through the use of telemedicine, or the establishment of call centres for giving instant advice on coping with a small emergency or advise as to which hospital to check into etc. Similar is the case regarding water management. All the relevant information hydrological, performance, planning – must be made available publicly on the web, which is widely being done in all the developed countries. The denial of information naturally leads to suspicions about “secret plans” and about incompetence and poor performance hiding behind the mantra of “national security”. Thus, increased investment in the basic hydrological data collection network is needed to provide information to prevent gross errors in water resources decision-making given the uncertainties of the distant future. On the other hand, the change will stimulate a chain reaction of accountability, participation, and demand for more and better data that would transform the culture of water management as well as the management of other services in the country. Improving Performance of Existing Agencies: One of the most critical factors responsible for the current breakdown of accountability relationships between the Government and the providers is the frequent transfer of civil servants, often for blatantly political motivations. There is no shortage of thinkers, policymakers, Government agency staff, politicians or academicians proposing ways to improve the public sector. Reducing transfers in the civil service, therefore, should be a priority issue on any reform agenda. Second major problem that Government agencies face is the overlapping of the regulatory and operational functions of policymakers and providers. This tends to diffuse these accountability relationships, particularly for infrastructure-dominated activities such as provision of water, sanitation, and electricity. Often the politics of patronage results in the provider losing its autonomy and acting as an extension of the policymaker. Similarly, providers may acquire political influence and capture the policymaking process 17 . In such circumstances, reform instruments that aim to separate the roles of the policymaker and provider can go a long way toward improving relations between the two. Regulatory functions could include delegation of responsibilities and finance; and information about performance and enforcement. Improving the Client-Provider Relationship: Improving service means making the interests of poor people matter more to providers. By engaging clients in an active role - as purchasers, as monitors, and as co-producers – the Government can improve performance of these services tremendously. Clients are usually in a better position to see what is going on than most of the supervisors in Government hierarchies. When the policymaker-provider link is weak because of scarce or difficult-to-manage supervisory staff, clients may be the only ones 16 United Nations - Water. 2006. “Enhancing Knowledge and Capacity”. In Water: A Shared Responsibility. The United Nations World Water Development Report 2. 17 World Development Report. 2004. Op.cit. pp. 159-79. 132 who regularly interact with the providers. For example, improvements in basic education have often depended on participation by parents. Although parents cannot monitor all aspects of education, they can monitor attendance by teachers and even illiterate parents can tell if their children are learning to read and write. Similarly, for some collective action problems, Governments may not be located at the correct level to solve them, no matter how willing they are to pursue the interests of the people. A more active role of communities is needed to ensure that everyone uses the service in a desirable manner at a given place. Conclusion Governments and providers have tried to make services that contribute to human development, work better for the people - in many cases they have succeeded in doing so. But too often, these services have failed in reaching out to the poor people. Services are failing because they are falling short of their potential to improve outcomes. They are often inaccessible or prohibitively expensive. But even when accessible, they are often dysfunctional, extremely low in technical quality, and unresponsive to the needs of a diverse clientele. The result of this is that many people bypass the closest public facility. They prefer going to more costly private facilities or choose a better quality of service at more distant public facilities. Also, innovation, and evaluation to increase productivity are rare. Thus, the Government should take the initiative or responsibility to make services work in order to promote health and education. Making services work requires improving the institutional arrangements through instituting regulations and rigorously monitoring their enforcement for producing the services. There needs to be a proper decentralization of powers from Centre to the States, to the districts by the States and from the districts to the multilayered local bodies. This has to be done with the appropriate devolution of duties, functions and finances. Creating a new information system using IT technology will result in greater transparency, accountability, and visibility. This will definitely alter the political power equations. It can challenge conventional wisdom on program performance, ensure new resource allocation decisions, and call into question the leadership of those responsible. On the other hand, the client power- the relationship between beneficiary and service provider - tends to be weak in many developing countries. Promoting or engaging clients in an active role - as purchasers, as monitors, and as co-producers - can improve performance of these services tremendously. 133 7 Summary of Conclusions and Policy Imperatives Introduction Non-tax revenue is a significant source of budgetary receipts for State Governments. Its importance is now being realized in the context of fiscal deficits and the heavy financial requirements for upgrading and modernizing basic infrastructure. It is also needed for human resources development. Non-tax revenues ensure that the sources of revenue to the State exchequer are broad-based and buoyant. Unlike tax revenues, in the case of non-tax revenues, the agencies of the Government first provide a service and then collect the user charges. The study began by giving the taxonomy of non-tax resources, where it is defined as payment made to the Government for which there is a quid pro quo. These are classified into three categories: (i) compulsory and requited payments; (ii) voluntary and unrequited payments; and (iii) voluntary and requited payments. However, to delimit the scope of this study, some of the non-tax sources have not been included in its analysis. Thus, the non-tax revenue in this study comprises revenue receipts, (i.e. non-capital receipts) excluding the accruals and taxes of all the tiers of the Government as well as the notional receipts matched by contra expenditures. A major part of non-tax revenue is raised through the collection of user charges, which are administratively determined for the goods and services provided by the Government. The Government intervention in the provision of these “public” goods and services is justified on the grounds of imperfect market conditions that prevail in the supply of these goods and services. However, economists have pointed out the sharp contrast between the pure economic theory of pricing and lack of its application in the real market. The marginal cost pricing principle, which is generally applicable for pricing of “private” goods, and services cannot be applied to “public” goods. Marginal cost pricing requires that there should be no externalities in consumption and production, and also presumes competitive forces operate throughout the economy. However, none of these conditions exist in the market. Also, the problems faced in marginal cost pricing get magnified due to equity and constitutional factors, as well the lack of accurate information and data. The study limits its scope to only those non-tax sources, which originate from the administrative departments and departmental undertakings that are of a commercial nature. Therefore, it does not take into account the sources such as interest, profits and dividends arising from the States’ commercial undertakings. The non-tax sources covered in the study include: the general services, social services and economic services. Of these, only ten major components of these services have been taken for an in-depth analysis. To conduct the study, data has been taken from Reserve Bank of India (RBI), State Budget Documents, Central Statistical Organisation, Bureau of Economics and Statistics, various State ministries dealing with different non-tax services etc. Fiscal Significance of States’ Own Non-tax Sources This chapter deals with the fiscal significance of the States’ own non-tax sources in India and in other countries. Trends in own non-tax revenue of the Indian States indicate that it has grown at the rate of 7.9 percent over the given period. However, when taken as a percent of aggregate receipts, it has declined from 11.6 percent in 1993-94 to 2.9 percent in 2003-04. The main constituents of the States own non-tax revenues are receipts from interests; dividends and profits; and the recoveries from general services, economic services and social services. As interest receipts, and dividends and profits can hardly be relied on for the growth in non-tax revenue receipts, it is the recoveries from services rendered by the Government which make a significant contribution to non-tax revenues. These constitute nearly two-third of the States’ own non-tax revenue. Of these, social services and economic services exhibited an upward trend with respect to the States’ Ontr, while general services showed considerable fluctuations. At the same time, general services receipts were the least consistent, followed by social services and economic services. In the case of general services, the revenue as a percent of States’ Ontr has shown an upward trend over the years, it registered an annual growth rate of 6.4 percent per annum. Also, its share in Ontr increased from the level of 18.9 percent in 1993-94 to 24.5 percent in 2003-04. Amongst the States (classified according to the level of income), in middle-income States the revenue from general services has been growing at the highest rate (18.3 percent,) while in high-income States the growth rate was 7.3 percent per annum. On the other hand, in the case of low-income States there was a negative growth rate of -5.0 percent. In 11 out of the 15 major States, revenue from general services displayed a rising trend. It showed a downward trend in rest of the States. Revenue contribution of social services was the least, but it grew at the highest rate as compared to the other services - at 14.5 percent per annum. It was also income-buoyant (1.2) at the all-State level. Amongst the major States, revenue from social services in West Bengal made the highest contribution to its Ontr (about 19.2 percent) in 1993-94, followed by Kerala, Tamil Nadu and Punjab. However, in 2003-04, Bihar had the highest revenue from social services, followed by Tamil Nadu etc. Among the major constituents of social services, (i.e. medical, public health and family welfare; education, arts and culture; urban development, and 135 water supply and sanitation), the revenue from medical, public health and family welfare was highest in the first period. However, by 2003-04, the revenue from education, sports, arts and culture became the chief contributor to the State exchequer. Economic services share in States’ Ontr exhibited a modest decline from 44.5 percent in 1993-94 to 43.4 percent in 2003-04. On an average, it contributed about 38.7 percent to the States’ Ontr which is very significant. The highest contribution to revenue from economic services came from the low-income States, followed by high-income and middle-income States. Amongst the major components of economic services, the share of industries and forestry & wildlife in revenue from economic services is the highest. Forestry is the second largest land-use in the country following agriculture and a major source of revenue from the forest department is from auctioning and sale of timber (a Government monopoly). On the other hand, revenue from industries constitutes about 40 percent revenue of economic services, of which the revenue from mines and minerals is the key contributing factor. Revenue from irrigation projects is also an important component of economic services. However, there exists a wide variation across the States in revenue receipts from irrigation. The problem related to cost recovery in irrigation can be attributed to poor agricultural performance; poor water delivery management by irrigation department; widespread corruption in irrigation projects etc. Nevertheless, nine States out of 15 major States have exhibited an improvement in revenue from irrigation for the given time period. Thus, the analysis of the States’ Ontr reveals that these are not fiscally significant in the States’ budget and their growth is not keeping pace with other components of revenue receipts. These have the potential of being a major source of revenue. The dire need is to take firm policy decisions and implement them so that this becomes a reality. Pricing Strategy for Non-tax Sources This chapter deals with the issue of pricing strategy that has been adopted in public utilities over time. The determination of user charges so as to have requisite cost recovery relates to the theory of utility pricing. This refers to the fixation of prices of goods and services provided by the Government (public sector) in order to maximize the benefits to the community. In answer to the question as to what services should be charged and through the adoption of which principle, Samuelson stated that pure public goods have to be financed through taxes while the quasi-public goods (those having one of the features of pure public goods) could be subsidized or regulated by the Government through a pricing mechanism. On the other hand, mixed goods may be financed partially by user charges and partly through a combination of subsidy and user charges. Based on these pricing principles and considering the Government as a natural monopoly, various models of utility pricing have been developed. These are marginal cost 136 (MC) pricing theory, average cost (AC) pricing theory and Price Discrimination theory (a combination of MC and AC pricing theories). Clark applied the MC pricing principle to the public utilities keeping in view the objectives of equity and efficiency. However, the application of the MC theory requires a number of restrictive assumptions. These restrictive assumptions are its limitations also and hence, MC pricing is not optimal. The other two feasible price theories are Boiteux and Ramsey pricing. The AC pricing principle is not efficient but ensures some profit margin. This approach estimates the total financial cost of providing a particular service divided by the total number of units using the service. However, there are certain problems in the estimation of this cost as the setting of such prices effectively require estimating the responsiveness of demand to price changes. Recovery of operating costs entails information on how unit costs change as the number of users change, as well as how the number of users will change as the price changes. Such information is not easy to obtain, and even if available, such prices are not likely to provide an efficient allocation of resources. In practice, these above stated principles may not result in desirable solutions. Therefore, a mix of them is applied for different utilities. Combinations of MC and AC pricing result in other models of utility pricing based on price discrimination, viz. economic pricing, fully distributed cost pricing, demand-compatible pricing, uniform pricing, non-uniform pricing, multi-part tariff, two-part tariff, myopic pricing rules, spot pricing etc. In determining the form of price discrimination, the effort is to see where and how these principles can be made applicable. Apart from these principles for pricing the utilities, the determination of user charges depends on certain factors. Properly designed user charges will often require the collection of complex and “difficult-to-obtain” information. The cost of collection of this necessary information or the cost of pricing may be so high as to make it unfeasible to apply user charges. Also, if the cost of collecting the charge exceeds the cost of providing the service, then no charge should be levied. An additional factor in determining user charges is the cost of changing public prices once they have been set. The prices set by the Government agency reflects the outcome of a political and administrative process and is not a pure “market” or economic process. These politically set prices are inherently “sticky” (or hard to change) and prevail only under a given political climate. User charges are sometimes perceived as a form of taxation but they differ as they are linked to specific benefits, which are over and above those enjoyed by the general public. These are designed to redefine Government priorities by incorporating more feedback from citizens with respect to the services they want and are willing to pay for. From this perspective, what matters is not just to impose charges but to levy the correct charges. RR/REs in Non-tax Sources As each State collect an appallingly low level of user charges, it needs to put in greater 137 effort to increase its own revenue. Thus, the Government needs to aim at appropriate cost recovery. This has to be done keeping in mind that the goods provided by them are characterised by externalities. There is also no clarity regarding the nature of these goods and services. However, fixation of user charges for non-tax sources is a complex issue. While rational user charges can generate means to achieve a greater growth rate, an irrational structure can cause adverse economic effects which invalidate growth objectives. Therefore, it is important to keep the objectives of equity, consumer acceptability, administrative feasibility, environmental issues etc. in view while fixing the user charges. In presenting the actual revenue realized as percent of revenue expenditure (RR/RE) for the select time period, this study has taken ten select services, which are public works, educations, sports, arts and culture; medical, public health and family welfare; water supply and sanitation; forestry and wild life; major and medium irrigation; minor irrigation; industries; mines and minerals; and roads and bridges. The RR/RE for the given time period, has risen only for two services in all the major States, viz. education, sports, arts and culture; and roads and bridges. In an attempt to determine the rate at which a service can increase its recovery, a desired RR/RE has been estimated using the regression technique. This desired RR/RE is an average of the State-wise desired RR/RE for each select service and will give a use all-States’ norm to be compared with actual RR/RE of each service across the States. In other words, the difference between the all-States’ rate of recovery for each select service (taken as the ‘Norm’) and the actual RR/RE of that particular service in each of the States will indicate the rate by which a State needs to make an effort to achieve that “desired” level. Issues in Delivery of Services Contemporary needs of the people significantly raise the pressure on the Government to deliver its services effectively and efficiently with respect to quantity and quality. However, these are greatly influenced by complexities in the procedure of delivery of services, resulting in undermining the real purpose of service delivery, especially its access to the needy. Thus, in education there is low accessibility by the poor due to its high cost, dysfunctional school and other constituents, low quality of education, low client responsiveness, and stagnant productivity. This indicates Government investment is not properly channeled. Similarly, medical and public health is facing problems of inadequate facilities, lack of doctors and other human resources, shortage of various instruments etc. compelling the client to prefer the private sector for acquiring these “public” facilities. Also, the Government health structure itself lacks co-ordination amongst different Ministries and bodies. This is another reason for its failure to sustain the integral nature of health care. The Government does not have a proper strategic vision to achieve the desired goal of a welfare State. Undoubtedly, the management of health care does not fulfill the required needs of the people. This is primarily due to low budget, irregular supplies of medicines, other 138 products and instruments; low salaries paid to the doctors; and the widespread prevalence of corrupt practices. Thus, the quality of services delivery is substandard. The same holds true for water supply and sanitation. All that is needed is a minimal level of integrity, fair play, and rule of law. These utility services require rational procedures in delivery of services and appropriate fiscal measures to supplement the existing need for that service. Proper regulation and enforcement is needed to raise awareness levels and to create a sense of accountability amongst providers regarding quality of the service. The publicly provided services have to be improved (in a competitive sense) in the market for such services. There is an urgent need to raise the performance of the existing bodies. This can be achieved effectively with the use of Information Technology (IT) to guide, monitor and correct the system thus ensuring efficient service delivery to the clients. The process of decentralisation can play a bigger role in service management. This will help in establishing good governance in the State at large and sufficiently ensure the existence of co-operation between the client (in getting the service) and the Government (in delivering the service), consequently, helping in strengthening the client-provider relationship. Thus the service delivery can be achieved efficiently, effectively and economically. Policy Imperatives In face of the severe revenue crunch for meeting revenue expenditure faced by all the States, there are few policy prescriptions for select services given for mobilising additional resources for planned development: Education: As education plays vital role in promoting socio-economic development of a country, it is of utmost importance that primary education is fully subsidized and user charges for secondary and higher education are so designed that these are progressive according to the income group of the user. Also, credit market should be regularized for financing higher education by making procedures simple so that it is accessible to both poor and non-poor. This would also help in increasing tuition fee collection to state exchequer. Medical and Public Health: Any increase in user charges for this service can result in lower recourse to medical services and higher rates of self-medication among the poor. Thus it is essential to differentiate between the poor and the non-poor availing the medical facilities. One way could be to locate more facilities closer to the rural areas, as most of the poor people live in rural areas, and charge zero or lower fees from them. On the other hand, insurance status is a good indicator of those people who can afford the medical care and so full cost should be charged from insured persons. Also, as demand for this facility is price inelastic, a little increase in user charge from non-poor would not affect the demand for the service. Water Supply and Sanitation: In this, water rate structure should be rationalized for better recovery of cost. Also, reasonably accurate metering system must be installed and maintained for those direct water users, and a timely billing and collection system has to be in 139 place. Also, there should be lower water rate charge for non-domestic users as compared to domestic users. Among the other things, accurate measurement of water on a volumetric basis is an important requisite for an effective pricing policy. With a view to improving resource use efficiency and sustainability of the environmental quality the following specific reforms could be useful: to increase the accountability of institutions to improve the reliability of service; to encourage private sector participation; to improve financial sustainability of the service; to create financial incentives to reduce O&M, capital and financing costs; to improve the environmental sustainability of service; and to have participation of the community groups. Forest and Wild life: There is a need to make a paradigm shift in raising revenue of the forest. This problem can be catapulted if an earmarked fund should be allocated to maintain the forest for a longer period of time. Some States have raised the issue of compensation for maintenance of forest cover to the Central Government. Also, the experiment of Joint Forest Management, as attempted in many of the States could be rewarding. Irrigation Projects: In irrigation projects increase in water rates was rather modest and State have not accepted, Irrigation Commission recommendations of reviewing and adjusting rates every five years. There is an urgent need to increase the user charge rates. Also, at present water rates are almost everywhere fixed crop wise and with reference to area irrigated. However, many considerations like linking water rates to quality of irrigation services, rationalizing rate structure and reducing cost of assessment and collection argue strongly for a system which makes water charges explicitly a function of volume and season. Thus, volumetric pricing should be adopted for better recovery of cost, though it can only be adopted in phased manner. Mines and Minerals: Royalty is an important source of non-tax revenue to the mineral producing States. However, if the rates of royalty remain unchanged for a long time, the real value of royalty declines significantly due to rising inflation and the States lose considerably. Thus, it is recommended that royalty rates should be increased with due interval of time. In addition, the royalty rates should be based on sale price system as against on quantity basis. Roads and Bridges: To improve the maintenance of roads it is recommended that the Government should start a system of electronic toll collection either through microwave technology or through infrared technology. This will be able to solve the problem of congestion due to toll collection. Microwave technology, which is commonly used throughout the world, is based on radio frequency waves, which will provide information to the toll collection plaza about the vehicle. Infrared, used mostly in remote controls, is relatively a new technology for toll collection. By using this technology, the processing of toll collection can be completed within a fraction of a second. 140 ANNEXURES Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Annexure A.1 I. Public Work Department I.a Machinery Hire Charges of the Public Works Department Without POL * Name of Machine 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 Idle 2002-03 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1.For Departmental Works Rollers Truck and Trailor Tractors and Trolly Trees and Plant Tar Boiler and Storage Stone Crushers and Granulators Water Pumps Generators Air Compressors Boring Machine Earth moving machinery Other machines * POL indicates petrol, oil and lubrication. 142 2003-04 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Without POL * Name of Machine 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 Idle 2002-03 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2. For Contractors Rollers Truck and Trailor Tractors and Trolly Trees and Plant Tar Boiler and Storage Stone Crushers and Granulators Water Pumps Generators Air Compressors Boring Machine Earth moving machinery Other machines 143 2003-04 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission II Education II. a Fee Rate Structure of Education Girls Boys Education Level for 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1. Non-Income Tax Payers upto Rs. 30000 p.a. (or BPL level) I to VIII Class IX Class X Class XI Class XII Class 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate LL.B. L.L.M. M. Phil Ph.D 144 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Girls Boys Education Level for 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Others 2.Non-Income tax Payers above Rs. 30000 p.a. I to VIII Class IX Class X Class XI Class XII Class 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate LL.B. L.L.M. M. Phil Ph.D Others 145 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Girls Boys Education Level for 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 3. Income tax Payers I to VIII Class IX Class X Class XI Class XII Class 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate LL.B. L.L.M. M. Phil Ph.D Others 146 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Girls Boys Education Level for 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 4. Students belonging to Scheduled Caste and scheduled Tribe I to VIII Class IX Class X Class XI Class XII Class 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate LL.B. L.L.M. M. Phil Ph.D Others 147 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission ii.b. Art & Culture Existing Visiting Fees to Museums and Archaeological Monuments Year Fees Visitors 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Rate for Ordinary tourist visits Non Student Student Visit for other purpose ( Filming purposes) Indian Foreign State Other Cultural Purposes TV Film Shooting Indian Foreign State 148 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Medical and Public Health Charges in the Public Hospitals (1) District Hospital (a) Outpatient Visits (i) Outpatient charges (ii) Laboratory tests (iii) Diagnostic tests (b) Charges for Inpatient services (i) Admission charges (ii) Surgery charges (iii) Delivery charges (iv) Inpatient stay charges (2) City Hospital (a) Outpatient Visits (i) Outpatient charges (ii) Laboratory tests (iii) Diagnostic tests (b) Charges for Inpatient services (i) Admission charges (ii) Surgery charges (iii) Delivery charges (iv) Inpatient stay charges (3) Specialty Hospital (a) Outpatient Visits (i) Outpatient charges (ii) Laboratory tests (iii) Diagnostic tests (b) Charges for Inpatient services (i) Admission charges 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 149 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission (ii) Surgery charges (iii) Delivery charges (iv) Inpatient stay charges (4) Village (area) hospital (a) Outpatient Visits (i) Outpatient charges (ii) Laboratory tests (iii) Diagnostic tests (5) Community health centre (a) Outpatient Visits (i) Outpatient charges (ii) Laboratory tests (iii) Diagnostic tests ( 6) Dispensaries (city) (a) Outpatient Visits (i) Outpatient charges (ii) Laboratory tests (iii) Diagnostic tests 150 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Existing Rates of Sanitation Years Items 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Domestic Rate Commercial Rate Industrial Rate Minimum Rate (applicable to all other categories) Existing Water supply rates for other than Irrigation purpose Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Items Urban areas Domestic Rate Commercial Rate Industrial Rate Minimum Rate (applicable to all other categories) Rural areas 151 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Domestic Rate Commercial Rate Industrial Rate Minimum Rate (applicable to all other categories) Other Purposes Brick making Laying/concrete/ and brick or stone masonry Metalling Roads Consolidation of Kutcha service Road - Water Supplies in bulk for:(a) Industrial purpose (b) drinking purpose © other purposes 152 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission IV. Forestry and Wild life Forest Products 1993-94 1994-95 Quantity Sold 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 Value Received 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Timber wood Timber wood Fuel wood Khair Sandalwood Teak Non-Timber Bamboo and resin Tendupatta Saaiseed Grass and Grazing Medicine & herbs Others 153 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission III. Major, Medium, and Minor Irrigation III. a Water Rates for Major and Medium, and Minor Irrigation Major & Medium Irrigation Name of Scheme 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 Minor Irrigation 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 A Scheme † (Water Rate) Name of the Crop (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii) (ix) † Scheme here refers to a particular irrigation plan/ project in the state. For example Indira Gandhi canal project in Rajasthan 154 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Major & Medium Irrigation Name of Scheme 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 Minor Irrigation 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 (x) B Scheme (Water Rate ) Name of the Crop (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii) (ix) (x) 155 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Major & Medium Irrigation Name of Scheme 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 Minor Irrigation 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 C Scheme (Water Rate) Name of the Crop (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii) (ix) (x) D Scheme (Water Rate) Name of the Crop 156 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Major & Medium Irrigation Name of Scheme 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 Minor Irrigation 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii) (ix) (x) E Scheme (Water Rate) Name of the Crop (i) (ii) 157 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Major & Medium Irrigation Name of Scheme 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 Minor Irrigation 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii) (ix) (x) 158 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission V. Industries Quantity Sold Types of Industries 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 Value Received 2002-03 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1. (Type of Product Sold) (i) (ii) (iii) 2. (Type of Product Sold) (i) (ii) (iii) 3 (Type of Product Sold) (i) (ii) (iii) 159 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission Quantity Sold Types of Industries 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 Value Received 2002-03 2003-04 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 4. (Type of Product Sold) (i) (ii) (iii) 5. (Type of Product Sold) (i) (ii) (iii) 6. (Type of Product Sold) (i) (ii) (iii) 160 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission VIII. Royalty Rate-Structure of Important Minerals Royalty Rates Minerals 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Major Minerals Minor Minerals 161 Foundation for Public Economics and Policy Research, Ashok Vihar, Delhi Phone: 011- 27305008, 27301758 ; Fax 011- 27302802, e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] Questionnaire for Collecting data for a Study on Non-tax Sources for Planned Development Sponsored by the Planning Commission IX. Roads and bridges Toll Tax Rates Rate per vehicle Categories of Vehicles 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 162 Annexure A.2 USER CHARGES IN SELECTED STATES PUBLIC WORKS DEPARTMENT Rajasthan A. 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Rollers NA NA NA 320 320 320 Truck and Trailor NA NA NA 1400 1400 1400 Tractors and Trolly NA NA NA 220 220 220 410 Without Petrol, Oil & Lubrication (POL) 1 2 B. For Departmental Works Trees and Plant NA NA NA 410 410 Tar Boiler and Storage NA NA NA 55 55 55 Stone Crushers and Granulators NA NA NA 650 650 650 Water Pumps NA NA NA 95 95 95 Generators NA NA NA 125 125 125 Air Compressors NA NA NA 290 290 290 Boring Machine NA NA NA 220 220 220 Earth Moving Machinery NA NA NA 375 375 375 Other Machines NA NA NA 615 615 615 Rollers NA NA NA 355 355 355 Truck and Trailor NA NA NA 1600 1600 1600 Tractors and Trolly NA NA NA 250 250 250 440 For Contractors Trees and Plant NA NA NA 440 440 Tar Boiler and Storage NA NA NA 85 85 85 Stone Crushers and Granulators NA NA NA 740 740 740 100 Water Pumps NA NA NA 100 100 Generators NA NA NA 130 130 130 Air Compressors NA NA NA 320 320 320 Boring Machine NA NA NA 245 245 245 Earth Moving Machinery NA NA NA 500 500 500 Other Machines NA NA NA 705 705 705 Idle 1 2 For Departmental Works Rollers NA NA NA 155 155 155 Truck and Trailor NA NA NA 400 400 400 Tractors and Trolly NA NA NA 100 100 100 Trees and Plant NA NA NA 180 180 180 Tar Boiler and Storage NA NA NA 0 0 0 Stone Crushers and Granulators NA NA NA 220 220 220 Water Pumps NA NA NA 75 75 75 Generators NA NA NA 80 80 80 Air Compressors NA NA NA 110 110 110 Boring Machine NA NA NA 145 145 145 Earth Moving Machinery NA NA NA 175 175 175 Other Machines NA NA NA 210 210 210 Rollers NA NA NA 0 0 0 Truck and Trailor NA NA NA 600 600 600 Tractors and Trolly NA NA NA 135 135 135 For Contractors 163 Trees and Plant NA NA NA 220 220 220 Tar Boiler and Storage NA NA NA 0 0 0 Stone Crushers and Granulators NA NA NA 355 355 355 Water Pumps NA NA NA 80 80 80 Generators NA NA NA 90 90 90 Air Compressors NA NA NA 145 145 145 Boring Machine NA NA NA 165 165 165 Earth Moving Machinery NA NA NA 0 0 0 Other Machines NA NA NA 210 210 210 Maharashtra Name of the Machine With POL (Rate in Rs.) 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 For Departmental Works Rollers (Per Hour) 7.5 Ton Trucks (Per K.M.) 186 197 15.25 137 Tractors and Trolly (Per Hour) 200 310.5 325 343 16.2 19 29.6 30.97 33 144 145 235 248 264 Trees and Plant Tar Boiler and Storage Stone Crushers and Granulators Water Pumps Generators Air compressors Boring Machine Earth Moving Machinery Other Machines Name of the Machine With POL (Rate in Rs.) 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 For Contractors Rollers (Per Hour) 7.5 Ton Trucks (Per K.M.) Tractors and Trolly (Per Hour) 225 238 242 376 393 415 18 20 23 36 37 40 166 174 175 284 300.08 319 Trees and Plant Tar Boiler and Storage Stone Crushers and Granulators Water Pumps Generators Air compressors Boring Machine Earth Moving Machinery Other Machines * POL indicates petrol, oil and lubrication 164 GENERAL EDUCATION, SPORTS AND ART & CULTURE Rajasthan III EDUCATION A. 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 NC NC NC NC NC NC IX Class 18 18 18 180 180 180 X Class 18 18 18 180 180 180 XI Class 48 48 48 360 360 360 XII Class 48 48 48 360 360 360 NC NC NC NC NC NC 84 84 84 360 360 360 360 BOYS 1 Non-Income Tax Payers (upto Rs. 30000 p.a.) I to VIII Class 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate L.L.B. L.L.M. M.Phil Ph.D Others 2 Non-Income Tax Payers (above Rs. 30000 p.a.) I to VIII Class IX Class X Class 84 84 84 360 360 XI Class 120 120 120 720 720 720 XII Class 120 120 120 720 720 720 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate L.L.B. L.L.M. M.Phil Ph.D Others 3 Income Tax Payers I to VIII Class NC NC NC NC NC NC IX Class 120 120 120 600 600 600 X Class 120 120 120 600 600 600 XI Class 180 180 180 1200 1200 1200 XII Class 180 180 180 1200 1200 1200 NC NC NC NC NC NC 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate L.L.B. L.L.M. M.Phil Ph.D Others 4 Students belonging to SC / ST I to VIII Class 165 IX Class NC NC NC NC NC NC X Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XI Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XII Class NC NC NC NC NC NC I to VIII Class NC NC NC NC NC NC IX Class NC NC NC NC NC NC X Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XI Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XII Class NC NC NC NC NC NC I to VIII Class NC NC NC NC NC NC IX Class NC NC NC NC NC NC X Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XI Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XII Class NC NC NC NC NC NC NC NC NC NC NC NC NC 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate L.L.B. L.L.M. M.Phil Ph.D Others B. GIRLS 1 Non-Income Tax Payers (upto Rs. 30000 p.a.) 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate L.L.B. L.L.M. M.Phil Ph.D Others 2 Non-Income Tax Payers (above Rs. 30000 p.a.) 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate L.L.B. L.L.M. M.Phil Ph.D Others 3 Income Tax Payers I to VIII Class IX Class NC NC NC NC NC X Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XI Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XII Class NC NC NC NC NC NC 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 166 3rd Years Post Graduate L.L.B. L.L.M. M.Phil Ph.D Others 4 Students belonging to SC / ST I to VIII Class NC NC NC NC NC NC IX Class NC NC NC NC NC NC X Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XI Class NC NC NC NC NC NC XII Class NC NC NC NC NC NC 2 2 5 5 5 5 NC NC 2 2 2 2 1st Years TDC 2nd Years TDC 3rd Years Post Graduate L.L.B. L.L.M. M.Phil Ph.D Others II.2 A. ART & CULTURE Rate for Ordinary Tourist Visits Non Student Student B. Visit for other purpose(Filming purposes) Indian 250 250 500 500 500 500 Foreign 500 500 1000 1000 1000 1000 State 125 125 250 250 250 250 5000 5000 15000 15000 15000 15000 10000 10000 20000 20000 20000 20000 2500 2500 10000 10000 10000 10000 C. Other Cultural Purposes D. TV Film Shooting Indian (per day charge) Foreign (per day charge) State (per day charge) NOTES: - NC: No Charge, NA: Data Not Available. 167 Punjab Existing Visiting Fees to Museums and Archaeological Monuments Visitors Fees in Rs. 1995-96 2000-01 Rate for Ordinary tourist Visits 2005-06 5 10 10 Non Student 5 5 5 Student 2 4 4 Visit for other Purpose(Filming Purpose) Indian Foreign State Other Cultural Purposes T V Film Shooting(Monument) 5000 (per day) Indian Foreign State Model Gallery PTA Student (Below 12 Years) Photography in museums 10 20 20 5 5 10 1000 (each) 1000 (each) MEDICAL AND PUBLIC HEALTH Rajasthan III 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Charges in the Public Hospitals A. District Hospital 1 Outpatient Visits i Outpatient Charges NC NC NC 2 2 2 ii Laboratory Tests NC NC NC 25 25 25 Diagnostic Tests 40 50 50 60 60 60 iii 2 Charges for Inpatient Services i Admission Charges NC NC NC 5 5 5 NC i Surgery Charges NC NC NC NC NC iii Delivery Charges NC NC NC NC NC NC iv Inpatient Stay Charges NC NC NC NC NC NC B. City Hospital 1 Outpatient Visits i Outpatient Charges NC NC NC 2 2 2 ii Laboratory Tests NC NC NC 25 25 25 Diagnostic Tests 40 50 50 60 60 60 iii 2 Charges for Inpatient Services i Admission Charges NC NC NC 5 5 5 NC ii Surgery Charges NC NC NC NC NC iii Delivery Charges NC NC NC NC NC NC iv Inpatient Stay Charges NC NC NC NC NC NC NC NC NC 2 2 2 C. Specialty Hospital 1 Outpatient Visits i Outpatient Charges 168 ii iii 2 Laboratory Tests NC NC NC 25 25 25 Diagnostic Tests 40 50 50 60 60 60 Charges for Inpatient Services i Admission Charges NC NC NC 5 5 5 NC ii Surgery Charges NC NC NC NC NC iii Delivery Charges NC NC NC NC NC NC iv Inpatient Stay Charges NC NC NC NC NC NC D. Village (area) Hospital 1 Outpatient Visits i Outpatient Charges NC NC NC NC NC NC ii Laboratory Tests NA NA NA NA NA NA Diagnostic Tests NA NA NA NA NA NA iii E. Community Health Centre 1 Outpatient Visits i Outpatient Charges NC NC NC 2 2 2 ii Laboratory Tests NA NA NA NC NC NC iii Diagnostic Tests NA NA 40 50 50 50 NC NC NC F. Dispensaries (city) 1 Outpatient Visits i Outpatient Charges NC NC NC ii Laboratory Tests NA NA NA NA NA NA iii Diagnostic Tests NA NA NA Notes: - Laboratory Tests mean TLC, DLC ESR, B.T., C.T. etc, Diagnostic Tests mean X-ray test. NA NA NA 169 WATER SUPPLY AND SANITATION Rajasthan Existing Rates of Water Supply (Water Charges) A. 199394 199495 199596 NA NA NA 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Gross Rate per 1000 litres (Rs.) 1 Domestic Rates i ii for consumption upto first 15000 litres for consumption exceeding 15000 litres and upto 40000 litres 1.56 1.56 1.56 NA NA NA 3.00 3.00 3.00 for next consumption above 40000 litres Minimum Charges per month for Domestic Category NA NA NA 4.00 4.00 4.00 i for 15 mm service line NA NA NA 20.00 20.00 20.00 ii for 20 mm service line NA NA NA 120.00 120.00 120.00 370.00 iii 2 iii for 25 mm service line NA NA NA 370.00 370.00 iv for 40 mm service line NA NA NA 870.00 870.00 870.00 v for 50 mm service line NA NA NA 1120.00 1120.00 1120.00 vi for 80 mm service line NA NA NA 2245.00 2245.00 2245.00 vi for 100 mm service line NA NA NA 4495.00 4495.00 4495.00 vii for 150 mm service line Flat Rate Charges for 15 mm domestic connection (unmetered) NA NA NA 11245.00 11245.00 11245.00 3 i for each connection per family upto two taps NA NA NA 20.00 20.00 20.00 ii for each additional tap NA NA NA Deleted Deleted Deleted NA NA NA 4.68 4.68 4.68 4 Non Domestic Rates i ii for consumption upto first 15000 litres for consumption exceeding 15000 litres and upto 40000 litres NA NA NA 8.25 8.25 8.25 for next consumption above 40000 litres Minimum Charges per month for Non Domestic Category NA NA NA 11.00 11.00 11.00 for 15 mm service line NA NA NA 51.00 51.00 51.00 ii for 20 mm service line NA NA NA 120.00 120.00 120.00 iii for 25 mm service line NA NA NA 370.00 370.00 370.00 iii 5 i iv for 40 mm service line NA NA NA 870.00 870.00 870.00 v for 50 mm service line NA NA NA 1120.00 1120.00 1120.00 vi for 80 mm service line NA NA NA 2245.00 2245.00 2245.00 vi for 100 mm service line NA NA NA 4495.00 4495.00 4495.00 vii for 150 mm service line NA NA NA 11245.00 11245.00 11245.00 6 Industrial Rates NA NA NA 11.00 11.00 11.00 i ii for consumption upto first 15000 litres for consumption exceeding 15000 litres and upto 40000 litres NA NA NA 13.75 13.75 13.75 for next consumption above 40000 litres Minimum Charges per month for Industrial Category NA NA NA 16.50 16.50 16.50 i for 15 mm service line NA NA NA 120.00 120.00 120.00 ii for 20 mm service line NA NA NA 240.00 240.00 240.00 480.00 iii 7 iii for 25 mm service line NA NA NA 480.00 480.00 iv for 40 mm service line NA NA NA 875.00 875.00 875.00 v for 50 mm service line NA NA NA 1125.00 1125.00 1125.00 vi for 80 mm service line NA NA NA 2250.00 2250.00 2250.00 vii for 100 mm service line NA NA NA 4500.00 4500.00 4500.00 viii for 150 mm service line NA NA NA 11250.00 11250.00 11250.00 8 Fixed Charges per month NA NA NA 10.00 10.00 10.00 9 Meter Service Charge per month 170 i for 15 mm service line NA NA NA 5.00 5.00 5.00 ii for 20 mm service line NA NA NA 15.00 15.00 15.00 iii for 25 mm service line NA NA NA 20.00 20.00 20.00 iv for 40 mm service line NA NA NA 30.00 30.00 30.00 v for 50 mm service line NA NA NA 40.00 40.00 40.00 vi for 80 mm service line NA NA NA 75.00 75.00 75.00 vii for 100 mm service line NA NA NA 125.00 125.00 125.00 viii for 150 mm service line NA NA NA 200.00 200.00 200.00 10 Sewerage Tax For PHED water supply 20% of the water charges mentioned above, wherever sewer system exists, subject to the usual rebate applicable for timely payment of water charges. For own water supply where PHED sewer system exists NA NA NA 31.25 31.25 31.25 (a) (b) i Hotel (per room / month) ii Restaurant (per month) NA NA NA 200.00 200.00 200.00 iii Cinema (per month) NA NA NA 400.00 400.00 400.00 iv For Car (truck service station per month) NA NA NA 200.00 200.00 200.00 v For Scooter service station per month For other industrial, commercial establishment per room per month NA NA NA 62.50 62.50 62.50 NA NA NA 12.50 12.50 12.50 Domestic Use Minimum charges for houses with plot area above 200 sq. mtr. the rates per 100sq. mtr. of the plot area Net Rate per 1000 litres allowing 20% rebate if payment is made within prescribed due date (Rs.) NA NA NA 12.50 12.50 12.50 NA NA NA 6.25 6.25 6.25 NA NA NA 1.25 1.25 1.25 vi vii (c) B. 1 Domestic Rates i ii iii 2 for consumption upto first 15000 litres for consumption exceeding 15000 litres and upto 40000 litres NA NA NA 2.40 2.40 2.40 for next consumption above 40000 litres Minimum Charges per month for Domestic Category NA NA NA 3.20 3.20 3.20 16.00 i for 15 mm service line NA NA NA 16.00 16.00 ii for 20 mm service line NA NA NA 96.00 96.00 96.00 iii for 25 mm service line NA NA NA 296.00 296.00 296.00 iv for 40 mm service line NA NA NA 696.00 696.00 696.00 v for 50 mm service line NA NA NA 896.00 896.00 896.00 vi for 80 mm service line NA NA NA 1796.00 1796.00 1796.00 vi for 100 mm service line NA NA NA 3596.00 3596.00 3596.00 vii for 150 mm service line Flat Rate Charges for 15 mm domestic connection (unmetered) NA NA NA 8996.00 8996.00 8996.00 3 i for each connection per family upto two taps NA NA NA 16 16 16 ii for each additional tap NA NA NA Deleted Deleted Deleted NA NA NA 3.75 3.75 3.75 NA NA NA 6.6 6.6 6.6 for next consumption above 40000 litres Minimum Charges per month for Non Domestic Category NA NA NA 8.8 8.8 8.8 41 4 Non Domestic Rates i ii iii 5 for consumption upto first 15000 litres for consumption exceeding 15000 litres and upto 40000 litres i for 15 mm service line NA NA NA 41 41 ii for 20 mm service line NA NA NA 96 96 96 iii for 25 mm service line NA NA NA 296 296 296 171 iv for 40 mm service line NA NA NA 696 696 696 v for 50 mm service line NA NA NA 896 896 896 vi for 80 mm service line NA NA NA 1796 1796 1796 vi for 100 mm service line NA NA NA 3596 3596 3596 vii for 150 mm service line NA NA NA 8996 8996 8996 6 Industrial Rates NA NA NA 8.8 8.8 8.8 i ii for consumption upto first 15000 litres for consumption exceeding 15000 litres and upto 40000 litres NA NA NA 11 11 11 for next consumption above 40000 litres Minimum Charges per month for Industrial Category NA NA NA 13.2 13.2 13.2 i for 15 mm service line NA NA NA 96 96 96 iii 7 ii for 20 mm service line NA NA NA 192 192 192 iii for 25 mm service line NA NA NA 384 384 384 iv for 40 mm service line NA NA NA 700 700 700 v for 50 mm service line NA NA NA 900 900 900 vi for 80 mm service line NA NA NA 1800 1800 1800 vi for 100 mm service line NA NA NA 3600 3600 3600 vii for 150 mm service line NA NA NA 9000 9000 9000 8 Fixed Charges per month NA NA NA 10 10 10 9 Meter Service Charge per month for 15 mm service line NA NA NA 5 5 5 i ii for 20 mm service line NA NA NA 15 15 15 iii for 25 mm service line NA NA NA 20 20 20 iv for 40 mm service line NA NA NA 30 30 30 v for 50 mm service line NA NA NA 40 40 40 vi for 80 mm service line NA NA NA 75 75 75 vii for 100 mm service line NA NA NA 125 125 125 viii for 150 mm service line NA NA NA 200 200 200 10 Sewerage Tax For PHED water supply 20% of the water charges mentioned above, wherever sewer system exists, subject to the usual rebate applicable for timely payment of water charges. For own water supply where PHED sewer system exists (a) (b) i Hotel (per room / month) NA NA NA 25 25 25 ii Restaurant (per month) NA NA NA 160 160 160 iii Cinema (per month) NA NA NA 320 320 320 iv For Car (truck service station per month) NA NA NA 160 160 160 v For Scooter service station per month For other industrial, commercial establishment per room per month NA NA NA 50 50 50 NA NA NA 10 10 10 Domestic Use Minimum charges for houses with plot area above 200 sq. mtr. the rates per 100sq. mtr. of the plot area NA NA NA 10 10 10 NA NA NA 5 5 5 vi vii (c) 172 Maharashtra Water Rates for Water Supply to Industrial Use (except Industries Mineral Water etc.) (Rs./10,000 liters.) Sr. No. from from from 1.7.2000 1.9.2001 1.7.2002 Type of Use Industrial Use A) If dam is constructed 1 From upstream of storage 10.9 22 25 2 From Canal(by gravity or lift) a) if storage tank is there as per yard sticks 21.8 45 51 b) if there is no storage tank as per yard sticks 27.25 54 62 3 From river down stream of dam a) as above 16.35 35 41 b) as above 27.25 54 62 If dam is constructed by the user agency or proportionate cost 4 of construction in proportion of water use is given 3.65 7.5 8.7 B) If there is no dam on river upstream to lifting point from river 3.65 7.5 8.7 from 1.7.2003 29 60 71.5 47 71 10 1 Water Rates for Water supply to Industrial use where water is used as raw material (e.g. cold drinks, bruaries, mineral water or similar for drinking purpose) (Rs./10,000 liters) Sr. No. Type of Use from 1.7.2000 from 1.9.2001 from 1.7.2002 from 1.7.2003 Industrial Use A) If dam is constructed across river 1 From upstream of storage 2 From Canal(by gravity or lift) 10.9 110 125 145 21.8 220 250 290 27.25 275 315 360 a) if storage tank is there as per yard sticks 16.35 165 190 220 b) if there is no storage tank as per yard sticks If dam is constructed by the user agency or proportionate cost of construction in proportion of water use is given 27.25 275 315 360 3.65 40 45 50 If there is no dam on river upstream to lifting point from river 3.65 40 45 50 a) if storage tank is there as per yard sticks b) if there is no storage tank as per yard sticks 3 4 B) From river down stream of dam Water Rates for water Supply for Domestic Use (Rs./10,000 liters.) Sr. No. Type of Use from 1.7.2000 from 1.9.2001 from 1.7.2002 from 1.7.2003 Industrial Use A) If dam is constructed across river 1 From upstream of storage 2 From Canal(by gravity or lift) 3 4 1.00 1.15 1.3 a) if storage tank is there as per yard sticks 1.2 2.5 3 3.25 b) if there is no storage tank as per yard sticks 1.8 3.5 4 5 0.95 From river down stream of dam a) if storage tank is there as per yard sticks B) 0.5 2 2.25 2.5 b) if there is no storage tank as per yard sticks If dam is constructed by the user agency or proportionate cost of construction in proportion of water use is given 1.8 3.5 4 5 0.35 0.75 1 1.15 If there is no dam on river upstream to lifting point from river 0.35 0.75 1 1.15 173 Orissa Existing Water Supply Rates for Other than Irrigation Purpose Years 1993-94 (in Rs.) 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Items Urban areas Domestic Rate per 1000 liters. 0.7 0.7 1.5 2.42 2.42 2.42 Commercial Rate per 1000 liters. 1.65 1.65 3.5 5.63 5.63 5.63 Industrial Rate per 1000 liters. Minimum Rate (applicable to all other categories) tap basis for domestic only 1.32 1.32 3 4.83 4.83 4.83 7.5 7.5 7.5 48 48 48 Rural areas Domestic Rate Commercial Rate Industrial Rate Minimum Rate(applicable to all other categories) Other Purposes Brick making Laying, concrete and brick or stone masonry Metaling Roads Consolidation of Kutcha Service Road Water supplies in bulk for a) Industrial Purpose b) Drinking Purpose c) Other Purpose Existing Rates of Water Supply and Sanitation (in Rs.) Years 1995-96 2000-01 2005-06 Items Domestic Rate 20 20 20 Commercial Rate 20 20 200(for 100mm dia sewer line) Industrial Rate 20 20 200(for 100mm dia sewer line) Flat Rate Minimum Rate(applicable to all other categories) 174 IRRIGATION RATES Rajasthan Gang Canal, Bhakra, Ghaggar, Rajasthan Canal, Chambal Canal (Irrigation under perennial channel (per acre) Pre-1952 Irrigation work except inundation irrigation work (per acre) Pre-1952 inundation works (per acre) Irrigation Rates (3-3-1982) Sl. No. Name of Crops 1 Sugarcane 58 50 21 2 Rice 40 23.1 10 3 Cotton 36 29 18 4 Maize 18 10 8 5 Bajara 18 10 8.06 6 Jawar 18 10 8 7 Pulses 21 18 13 8 Garden (per year) 73 49 23 9 Guwar 21 18 10 10 Simmhemp & Grass 18 18 13 11 Vegetables 29 20 11 12 Other Kharif Crop 23 18 13 13 Wheat 30 21 13 14 Barley 21 15 10 15 Gochani & Bejar 29 21 15 16 Gram (1st Watering) 20 18 10 (or more watering) 29 25 18 Palewa 9 6 18 Fodder 18 18 19 Oil seeds 23 18 13 20 Water Nuts 36 25 13 21 Indigo & other dyes 36 18 13 22 Tobacco 36 21 13 23 Lucerne & Poppy 36 21 11 24 Zeera 36 19 11 25 Other Rabi crops 26 18 13 17 Gang Canal, Bhakra, Ghaggar, Rajasthan Canal, Chambal Canal (Irrigation under perennial channel (per acre) Pre-1952 Irrigation work except inundation irrigation work (per acre) .10 Pre-1952 inundation works (per acre) Table of Irrigation Rates (24-051999) Sl. No. Name of Crops 1 Sugarcane 100 116 2 Rice 46 80 20 3 Cotton 58 72 36 4 Maize 15 27 12 5 Wajara 15 27 12 6 Jawar 15 27 12 7 Pulses 27 32 20 8 Garden (per year) 98 146 46 9 Guwar 27 32 15 10 Simmhemp & Grass 27 27 20 11 Vegetables 30 44 17 12 Other Kharif Crop 36 46 26 13 Wheat 42 60 26 14 Barley 23 32 15 15 Gochani & Bejar 32 44 23 16 Gram (1st Watering) 27 30 27 42 175 Karnataka Major, Medium and Minor Irrigation Rates Name of Scheme: Flow Irrigation Table of Major, Medium and Minor Irrigation Rates (Rs./Acre) Name of the crop 1 2 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 Sugarcane (within 12 months 150 150 150 12 months within 18 months 225 225 225 2002-03 2003-04 400 400 400 100 100 100 60 60 60 35 35 35 Paddy (for 1st crop) 35 35 35 (for 2nd & subsequent crops) 40 40 40 2 Wheat&Sunflower 22 22 22 3 Groundnut 24 24 24 4 Cotton 40 40 40 5 Jowar 20 20 20 6 Maize, Navane, Ragi & Srmi dry crops 20 20 20 7 Pulses 15 15 15 35 35 35 8 Tobacco 24 24 24 35 35 35 Garden crops 40 40 40 60 60 60 8 8 8 15 15 15 9 10 Manurial crops 11 Other crops 20 20 20 35 35 35 Note: Water rate for lift irrigation schemes are 3 times the water rates flow irrigation schemes for Paddy and Sugarcane and 2 times the water rates of flow irrigation for crops other than paddy and sugarcane. Maharashtra Revised Water Rates for Canal Flow Water Use by Different Crops by Different Seasons (on major, medium & minor projects) Sr.No. Name of Crop of Season A). (water rates in Rupees per hectare) from from from 1/7/00 1/9/01 1/7/02 from 1/7/03 Kharif season 1 Kharif seasonal (including hybrid), 120 180 207 238 Kharif rice (on contract) 2 Kharif rice (on demand) Kharif groundnut hybrid seeds and kharif support crops 240 360 414 476 3 Advance watering (in kharif season for rabi crops) 60 90 104 119 B). Rabi season 4 Rabi seasonal (excluding wheat and groundnut) 180 270 311 357 5 Rabi wheat Kharif & rabi Cotton , rabi groundnut rabi-HW rice, hybrid seeds & rabi support crops Late watering (given for kharif crops in rabi season) 240 360 414 476 365 548 630 724 60 90 104 119 6 7 C). Hot weather season 8 Hot weather seasonal 365 548 630 724 9 HW groundnut, HW Cotton (from April 1) 725 1088 1251 1438 HW Cotton (from March 1) Advance watering (1 watering given in Hot weather season) Late watering (1 watering given in HW for rabi crops) 970 1455 1673 1924 180 270 311 357 90 135 155 178 In Kharif & rabi 180 270 311 357 In rabi & hot weather 305 458 526 605 10 11 12 D). Two seasonal crops 13 E). Two seasonal e.g. Tur, Potato etc Perennials(flow) 176 14 Sugarcane and Banana 15 16 Fruit crops, Lucerne etc. sugar beet(excluding advance & late irrigation given), rabi vegetables 17 Kharif vegetables 18 20 Hot weather vegetables Onion in Kharif & rabi seasons, Onion in Kharif & rabi seasons, given with one late irrigation Onion in Kharif & rabi seasons and in HW season given more than one irrigation 21 Onion in rabi and HW season F). 3175 4763 5477 6297 3175 4763 5477 6297 1081 Other Perennials(flow) 545 818 940 365 548 630 724 1360 2040 2346 2697 910 1365 1570 1805 1270 1905 2191 2519 1450 2175 2501 2876 Kharif 155 233 267 307 Rabi 265 398 457 526 23 Adsali in January 635 953 1095 1259 24 Adsali in February 690 1035 1190 1368 25 Adsali in March 1200 1800 2070 2380 26 Adsali in April 1490 2235 2570 2955 27 Suru upto February for every month 265 398 457 526 28 Suru in March 910 1365 1570 1805 29 Suru in April 1055 1583 1820 2092 19 G). Extended(flow) 22 H). Adsali upto December for every month Crop Block rates(flow) 30 Sugarcane block 1:4 1045 1568 1803 2073 31 Fruit block 3175 4763 5477 6297 32 Garden block 1235 1853 2130 2449 33 Garden seasonal block 1325 1988 2286 2628 34 Three seasonal block, two seasonal block 455 683 785 902 35 Rabi block 320 480 552 635 2920 3180 3657 4205 2920 3180 3657 4205 I) Perennials(Drip & Sprinkler) 36 Sugarcane & Banana 37 38 Fruit crops, Lucerne etc. Sugar beet(excluding advance & late irrigation given) 365 548 630 724 39 Kharif vegetables 240 360 414 476 40 rabi Vegetables 365 548 630 724 41 Hot weather Vegetables 910 1365 1570 1805 42 605 908 1044 1200 665 998 1147 1319 44 Onion in Kharif & rabi seasons Onion in Kharif & rabi seasons given with one late irrigation Onion in Kharif & rabi seasons & in HW season given more than one irrigation 850 1275 1466 1686 45 Onion in rabi and HW seasons 970 1455 1673 1924 Kharif 105 158 181 208 Rabi 175 263 302 347 47 Adsali in January 425 638 733 843 48 Adsali in February 460 690 794 912 49 Adsali in March 800 1200 1380 1587 50 Adsali in April 990 1485 1708 1963 51 Suru upto February for every month 175 263 302 347 52 Suru in March 605 908 1044 1200 53 Suru in April 705 1058 1216 1398 J) Other Perennials(Drip & Sprinkler) 43 K) Extended irrigation(drip & sprinkler) 46 Adsali upto December for every month 177 L) Crop Block rates(drip & sprinkler) 54 Sugarcane block 1:4 55 Fruit block 700 1050 1208 1388 2120 3180 3657 4205 56 Garden block 825 1238 1423 1636 57 Garden seasonal block 885 1328 1527 1755 58 Three seasonal block, two seasonal 305 458 526 605 59 Rabi block 215 323 371 426 60 Sugarcane 5900 8850 10178 11701 61 Other perennials 4990 7485 8608 9897 62 Kharif seasonal 240 360 414 476 63 Rabi seasonal 365 548 630 724 64 Wheat 515 773 888 1021 65 Hot weather crops, rice (follow on) 910 1365 1570 1805 66 Cotton , groundnut 1270 1905 2191 2519 N) Water rates for sewage water Water rates/royalty rates for water supplied on volumetric basis from canals/from reservoirs constructed from funds of water users. (Rs. per thousand cubic meter) Rates of from from from 01/07/00 1/9/01 1/7/02 1/7/03 Sr.No. Location Season 1 1 2 3 2 From canal at minor head(water rates) 3 From canal at outlet (water rates) Reservoir constructed by water users (royalty charges) 4 5 6 7 Kharif 24 36 41.4 47.6 rabi 36 54 62.1 71.4 hot weather 73 109.5 125.9 144.8 Kharif 27 40.5 46.6 53.6 rabi 40 60 69 79.4 hot weather 80 120 138 158.7 For all seasons 12 18 20.7 23.8 Water Rates for Lift Irrigation Schemes from 01-07-2001 (for Water Use of Private Lift Irrigation Scheme) (Rs. per hector) Sr.No. Location of lift irrigation Sugarcane & Banana drip irrigation flow 1 1 2 3 4 2 Canal Reservoir/dam/elevated bandhara Within boundaries of command area in back water areas of river bandharas where dam water is not released First bandhara on river/nalla or lift irrigation from areas beyond dam, diversion bandhara in kharif Kharif crops Other perennials Rabi crops Hot weather drip irrigation flow 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1495 995 995 665 65 100 200 755 495 500 330 35 50 100 375 255 255 165 30 30 50 125 75 80 55 nil 20 20 178 Water rates for lift irrigation Schemes from 01-07-2002(for water use of private lift irrigation scheme) (Rs. per hector) Sugarcane & Banana Sr.No. Other perennials Kharif crops Location of lift irrigation flow 1 2 1 Canal 2 3 Reservoir/dam/elevated bandhara Within boundaries of command area in back water areas of river bandanas where dam water is not released First bandhara on river/nalla or lift irrigation from areas beyond dam, diversion bandhara in kharif 4 drip irrigation flow Rabi crops Hot weather drip irrigation 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1645 1095 1090 730 75 110 220 825 555 550 365 35 55 110 410 280 280 180 30 30 55 135 80 90 60 nil 20 20 Water rates for lift irrigation Schemes from 01-07-2003(for water use of private lift irrigation scheme) (Rs. per hector) Other perennials Sugarcane & Banana Sr.No. Location of lift irrigation flow 1 1 2 3 4 2 Canal Reservoir/dam/elevated bandhara Within boundaries of command area in back water areas of river bandharas where dam water is not released First bandhara on river/nalla or lift irrigation from areas beyond dam, diversion bandhara in kharif drip irrigation flow Kharif crops Rabi crops Hot weather drip irrigation 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1810 1205 1200 805 85 120 240 910 610 605 400 40 60 120 450 310 310 200 35 35 60 150 90 100 65 nil 20 20 179 Service Charge for lift irrigation schemes above 30 meters under jurisdiction of Irrigation Department and Irrigation Development Corporation (Rupees per hectare) Sr. No. Rates of 01/07/00 Season and Crops name 1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 2 From 01/09/01 From 01/07/02 From 01/07/03 3 4 5 6 1) Tur 250 375 431 496 2) Turmeric/Chillies 3) LS cotton and Groundnut(hot weather & kharif) 345 518 595 685 725 1088 1251 1439 Two seasonal Crops Perennial crops(flow) 1) Sugarcane/banana 3290 4935 5675 6531 2) Other perennial crops 3) Extended cane & banana(rate for one watering) 2290 3435 3950 4556 115 173 198 228 1) Sugarcane/banana 2195 3293 3786 4357 2) Other perennial crops 3) Extended cane & banana(rate for one watering) 1525 2288 2631 3027 75 113 129 149 526 Perennial crops(drip) Kharif crops 1) Rice 265 398 457 2) Other food grain and fodder crops 150 225 259 298 3) Other cash crops 210 315 362 417 1) Wheat 335 503 578 665 2) Other food grain and fodder crops 200 300 345 397 3) Other cash crops 425 638 733 844 1) Cash crops 725 1088 1251 1439 2) Follow on hot weather rice 835 1253 1440 1657 1) Kharif 280 420 483 556 2) Rabi crops 425 638 733 844 3) Hot weather Advance and late watering (each watering) 725 1088 1251 1439 Rabi crops Hot weather crops Vegetables 1) Food grain crops 50 75 86.3 99.2 2) Cash crops 65 98 112.1 128.9 180 Service Charge for lift irrigation schemes below 30 meters under jurisdiction of Irrigation Department and Irrigation Development Corporation Sr. No. Season and Crops name 1 1 2 3 4 5 2 7 8 From 01/07/03 3 4 5 6 1) Tur 240 360 414 476 2) Turmeric/Chillies 3) LS cotton and Groundnut(hot weather & kharif) 335 503 578 664 605 908 1044 1200 Two seasonal Crops Perennial crops(flow) 1) Sugarcane/banana 2725 4088 4701 5405 2) Other perennial crops 3) Extended cane & banana(rate for one watering) 1880 2820 3243 3729 90 135 155.3 178.5 1) Sugarcane/banana 1815 2723 3131 3600 2) Other perennial crops 3) Extended cane & banana(rate for one watering) 1255 1883 2165 2489 60 90 103.5 119 Perennial crops(drip) Kharif crops 1) Rice 180 270 311 357 2) Other food grain and fodder crops 150 225 259 297 3) Other cash crops 210 315 362 416 270 405 466 535 Rabi crops 1) Wheat 6 (Rupees per hectare) From From 01/09/01 01/07/02 Rates of 01/07/00 2) Other food grain and fodder crops 180 270 311 357 3) Other cash crops 425 638 733 843 Hot weather crops 1)Hot Weather food grains/hybrid jowar 365 548 630 724 2) Cash crops 605 908 1044 1200 3) Follow on hot weather rice 455 683 785 902 1) Kharif 270 405 466 535 2) Rabi crops 425 638 733 843 3) Hot weather Advance and late watering (each watering) 605 908 1044 1200 1) Food grain crops 50 75 86.3 99.2 2) Cash crops 65 97.5 112.1 128.9 Vegetables West Bengal The water rates prevailing in West Bengal since 1.7.1977 are uniform throughout the state in all project which are as follows: Season Kharif Rabi Boro Rate per ha. Rs. 37.06 Rs. 49.42 Rs. 123.55 181 STATE WISE POSITION ON OTHER LEVIES/CESSES ON IRRIGATION AREA State/ Item 1 1) Karnataka 2) Maharashtra Water Rate* 2 Yes Yes Betterment Levy 3 3) Rajasthan 4) West Bengal Yes Yes Rs. 400(for cultivable lands) Rs. 570(for waste lands) (Rate Rs. per ha) Any Other Charges having bearing on Irrigation 6 Irrigation Cess 4 Crop Cess 5 Local Cess on Water rates @ 20 paise per rupee Education Employment Guarantee Cess (a) Education Cess: i) Sugarcane=Rs.190 per ha. ii) Banana= Rs.110 iii) Cotton=Rs.40 iv) Groundnut=Rs. 40 (b) Employment guarantee Cess at Rs.25 per ha. on all agricultural lands on which irrigated crop are grown. - - - * Water Rate of these States is given above this table. INDUSTRIES Rajasthan VIII 1993-94 INDUSTRIES A. 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 Quantity sold 1 Salt (in quintals) 2 Crude (in metric tonnes) 3 Textile (in lakhs kgs) B. 378905.6 1392875 1585470 Pvt Pvt Pvt 2617 2887 4137 4324 1913 1443 181.87 172.3 180.01 98.78 136.79 95.51 57.83 199.2 219.9 Pvt Pvt Pvt 21.2 18.01 27.76 32.44 14.71 9.09 8829.86 11917.11 13586.2 7388.69 9599.4 9029.62 Value Received (Rs. in lakhs) 1 Salt 2 Crude(M.T.) 3 Textile MINES AND MINERALS Rajasthan MINES AND MINERALS IX Royalty Rate Structure of Important Minerals A. 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 Agate Major Minerals NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad i Apatite NA NA NA 5% ad 5% ad 5% ad ii Rock Phosphate: Above 25% P2O5 NA NA NA 11% ad 11% ad 11% ad Upto 25% P2O5 NA NA NA 5% ad 5% ad 5% ad Chrysotile (Rs. per tonne) Amphibole (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 726 726 726 NA NA NA 35 35 35 Barytes Bauxite, Laterite (percent of London Metal Exchange Aluminum metal price chargeable on the contained aluminum metal in ore produced) NA NA NA 5.5% ad 5.5% ad 5.5% ad NA NA NA 0.35% 0.35% 0.35% 1 2 (a) (b) 3 (b) 5 2002-03 2003-04 Asbestos: (a) 4 2001-02 182 6 Brown Ilmenite(Leucoxene), Ilmenite,Rutile and Zircon NA NA NA 2% ad 2% ad 2% ad 7 Cadmium NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad 8 Calcite Chinaclay/Kaolin(inc ballclay, white shale & white clay) NA NA NA 15% ad 15% ad 15% ad Crude (Rs. per tonne) Processed (washed) (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 21 21 21 NA NA NA 75 75 75 Chromite NA NA NA 7.5% ad 7.5% ad 7.5% ad Coal Coal produced in all States & Union Territories except the State of West Bengal Group I Coals: (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 250 250 250 NA NA NA 165 165 165 NA NA NA 115 115 115 NA NA NA 85 85 85 NA NA NA 65 65 65 NA NA NA 65 65 65 NA NA NA 50 50 50 NA NA NA 90 90 90 9 (a) (b) 10 11 A. i (a) Coking Coal Steel Grade-I Steel Grade-II (b) ii (a) (b) (c) (d) iii (a) (b) iv (a) (b) v (a) (b) vi Washery Grade-II Hand picked coal produced in the States of Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Meghalaya and Nagaland Group II Coals: (Rs. per tonne) Coking Coal Washery Grade-II Coking Coal Washery Grade-III Semi-Coking Coal GradeI Semi-Coking Coal GradeII Non-Coking Coal Grade A Non-Coking Coal Grade B Ungraded Run of Mine Coal produced in the States of Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Meghalaya and Nagaland Group III Coals: (Rs. per tonne) Coking Coal Washery Grade-IV Non-Coking Coal Grade C Group IV Coals: (Rs. per tonne) Non-Coking Coal Grade D Non-Coking Coal Grade E Group V Coals: (Rs. per tonne) Non-Coking Coal Grade F Non-Coking Coal Grade G Lignite Group VI Coals: (Rs. per tonne) 183 B. i (a) Coal produced in all State of Andhra Pradesh Coal produced in the State of West Bengal Group I Coals: (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 7 7 7 NA NA NA 6. 5 6. 5 6. 5 NA NA NA 5. 5 5. 5 5. 5 NA NA NA 4. 3 4. 3 4. 3 NA NA NA 2. 5 2. 5 2. 5 Coking Coal Steel Grade-I Steel Grade-II ii (a) (b) (c) iii (a) (b) iv (a) (b) v (a) (b) 12 Washery Grade-I Group II Coals: (Rs. per tonne) Coking Coal Washery Grade-II Coking Coal Washery Grade-III Semi-Coking Coal GradeI Semi-Coking Coal GradeII Non-Coking Coal Grade A Non-Coking Coal Grade B Group III Coals: (Rs. per tonne) Coking Coal Washery Grade-IV Non-Coking Coal Grade C Group IV Coals: (Rs. per tonne) Non-Coking Coal Grade D Non-Coking Coal Grade E Group V Coals: (Rs. per tonne) Non-Coking Coal Grade F Non-Coking Coal Grade G Copper (percent of London Metal Exchange copper metal price chargeable on the contained copper metal in ore produced) NA NA NA 3.20% 3.20% 3.20% 13 Corundum NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad 14 Diamond NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad 15 Dolomite (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 40 40 40 16 Felspar Fireclay (inc plastic, pipe, lithomargic and natural pozzolanic clay) Fluorspar (also called fluorite) NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad NA NA NA 12% ad 12% ad 12% ad NA NA NA 5% ad 5% ad 5% ad 17 18 19 Garnet: (a) Abrasive NA NA NA 3% ad 3% ad 3% ad (b) Gem NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad Gold: Primary (percent of London price chargeable on the contained gold metal in ore produced) By-product gold (percent of London price chargeable on by-product gold metal actually NA NA NA 1.50% 1.50% 1.50% NA NA NA 2.50% 2.50% 2.50% 20 (a) (b) 184 produced) 21 (a) (b) (c) Graphite: With 80% or more fixed carbon (Rs. per tonne) With 40% or more but less than 80% fixed carbon (Rs. per tonne) With less than 40% fixed carbon (Rs. per tonne) 22 Gypsum 23 Iron ore: i (a) (b) (c) (d) ii (a) (b) (c) iii 24 26 (a) (b) 27 28 29 30 32 33 34 Fines With 65% Fe content or more (Rs. per tonne) With 62% Fe content or more but less than 65% Fe (Rs. per tonne) With less than 62% Fe content (Rs. per tonne) Concentrates prepared by beneficiation and/or concentration of low grade ore containing 40% Fe or less (Rs. per tonne) Kyanite Lead (percent of London Metal Exchange Lead, metal price chargeable on the contained lead metal in ore produced) 25 31 Lumps With 65% Fe content or more (Rs. per tonne) With 62% Fe content or more but less than 65% Fe (Rs. per tonne) With 60% Fe content or more but less than 62% Fe (Rs. per tonne) With less than 60% Fe content (Rs. per tonne) Limestone: L.D. grade (less than one and half percent silica content) (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 225 225 225 NA NA NA 130 130 130 NA NA NA 50 50 50 NA NA NA 20% ad 20% ad 20% ad NA NA NA 24.5 24.5 24.5 NA NA NA 14.5 14.5 14.5 NA NA NA 10 10 10 NA NA NA 7 7 7 NA NA NA 17 17 17 NA NA NA 10 10 10 NA NA NA 7 7 7 NA NA NA 3 3 3 NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad NA NA NA 5% 5% 5% NA NA NA 50 50 50 Others (Rs. per tonne) Lime Kankar (Rs. per tonne) Limeshell (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 40 40 40 NA NA NA 40 40 40 NA NA NA 40 40 40 Magnesite NA NA NA 3% ad 3% ad 3% ad Manganese Ore: (a) Ore of all Grades NA NA NA 3% ad 3% ad 3% ad (b) Concentrates Crude Mica, Waste and Scrap Mica Monazite (Rs. per tonne) Nickel (percent of London Metal Exchange nickel, metal price chargeable on the contained nickel metal in ore produced) NA NA NA 1% ad 1% ad 1% ad NA NA NA 4% ad 4% ad 4% ad NA NA NA 125 125 125 NA NA NA 0.12% 0.12% 0.12% Ochre (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 12 12 12 185 35 Pyrites NA NA NA 2% ad 2% ad 2% ad 36 Pyrophyllite Quartz, silica sand, moulding sand and quartzite (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 15% ad 15% ad 15% ad NA NA NA 15 15 15 38 Ruby NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad 39 Sand for Stowing 40 Selenite NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad 41 Sillimanite NA NA NA 2.5% ad 2.5% ad 2.5% ad NA NA NA 5% 5% 5% 5% 37 42 (a) (b) Silver: By-product (percent of London price chargeable on by-product silver metal actually produced) Primary Silver (percent of London Metal Exchange silver metal price chargeable on the contained silver metal in ore produced) NA NA NA 5% 5% 43 Slate (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 40 40 40 44 Talc/Steatite/Soapstone: Tin (percent of London Metal Exchange tin metal price chargeable on the contained tin metal in ore produced) Tungsten (Rs. per unit percent of contained WO3 per tonne of ore and on pro rata basis) NA NA NA 15% ad 15% ad 15% ad NA NA NA 5% 5% 5% NA NA NA 20 20 20 45 46 47 Uranium NA NA NA 5* 5* 5* 48 Vermiculite NA NA NA 3% ad 3% ad 3% ad 49 Wollastonite Zinc (percent of London Metal Exchange Zinc metal price chargeable on the contained Zinc metal in ore produced) All other minerals not herein before specified Minor Minerals (Rs. per tonne) NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad NA NA NA 6.60% 6.60% 6.60% NA NA NA 10% ad 10% ad 10% ad 55 50 51 B. i Sandstone NA 45 45 55 55 ii Limestone NA 45 45 50 50 50 iii Marble serpentine NA 100 100 250 250 250 iv Granite Chips & powder making minerals NA 75 75 100 100 100 NA 18 18 40 40 40 vi Masonary Stone NA 5 5 5 5 5 vii Bajri Kankar Brick earth, Murram Surkhi NA 5 5 6 6 6 NA 5 5 6 6 6 ix Phyllite & Sehist NA 12 12 15 15 15 x Fuller's earth NA 25 25 35 35 35 xi Bentonite NA 35 35 45 45 45 v viii xii Salt Stone NA 25 25 36 36 36 Notes:- Pvt: Privatised, ad: Sale price on ad valorem basis, * Rupees for dry ore with U3O8 content of 0.05% with pro rat increase/decrease at the rate of Rs. 1.50 per metric tonne of ore for 0.01% increase /decrease 186 Karnataka ROYALTY RATE-STRUCTURE OF IMPORTANT MINERALS Major Minerals Royalty Rates 1993-94 Maior Minerals w.e.f. 17-2-1992 1994-95 Same as 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 11/4/1997 12/9/2000 0.40% of LME 15% of sale price Rs.23/- 1993-94 1) Bauxite & Laterite Rs. 34/- . Rs.41/- 2) Calcite Rs.41/- Rs.48/ 0.35% of LME 15% of sale price Rs.14/- Rs.18/- Rs.21/- P.T. Same as 14-10- 2001-02 2004 3) China Clay 1 Kaolin a) Crude b) Processed 4) Chromite Rs.62/- Rs.68/- Rs.75/- P.T. Rs.85/- Rs.23 to Rs. 250/- 7 .5% of sale price 7 .5% of sale price 7 .5% of sale price 5) Copper 6) Corrundum Rs. 17/- per ton Rs.210/- 0.75% of LME Rs.231/- 3.2% of LME 10% of sale price 3.2% of LME 10% of sale price 7) Dolomite 8) Felspar Rs.25/- P.T. Rs.15/- Rs.28/- P.T. Rs.17/- 9) Fire Clay Rs.13/- Rs.17/- Rs.40/- P.T. 10% of sale price 12% of sale price Rs.45/- P.T. 10% of sale price 12% of sale price 1.5% of LME 1.5% of LME 2.5% LME 2.5% of LME 10) Gold a) Primary Rs.l1/-per gm. b) By product gold RS.10/-per gm. 1.5% of sale price 2.5% of sale price 11) Iron ore Lumps a) 65% Fe or more Rs.18/- Rs.21.50 Rs.24.50 Rs.27/- b) 62% - 65% Rs.l0/- Rs.12/- Rs.14.50 Rs.16/- c) 60% - 62% Rs.7/- Rs.8.50 Rs.10.00 Rs.11/- d) Less than 60% Rs.5/- Rs.6/- Rs. 7 -00 a) 65% Fe or more. Rs.13/- Rs.15.50 Rs.17.00 b) 62% - 65% Rs.7/- Rs. 8.50 Rs.10.00 Rs.11/- c) Less than 62% Rs.5/- Rs.6-00 Rs.7-00 Rs.8/- Concentrates Rs.2.25 Rs.2.5 Rs.3.00 12) Kyanite Rs. 85/- 10% of sale price Rs.4/10% of sale price 13) Lime stone a) LD Grade (less than 1.5 % of silica) Rs.50/- Rs.50/- Rs.50/- Rs.55/- b) Others Rs. 25/- Rs.32/- Rs40/- Rs.45/- 14) Lime Kankar Rs.50/- Rs.50/- Rs.40/ - Rs.45/- 15) Lime shell Rs.25/- Rs.28/- Rs.40/- Rs.45/- Rs.107/- Rs.112/- 3.5 % of sale price 3% of sale price Rs.2/- 1.5% of sale price 1% of sale price Rs.12/- Rs.13/- Rs.15/- Rs.20/- Rs.3.40 per kg of metal 5% of sale price 5% of LME 5% of LME Fines Rs.19/- 16) Manganese Ore a) All grades b) Concentrates 17) Quartz, Silica Sand, Moulding sand &Quartzite 18) Silver a) By product 187 b) primary Silver Rs.3.40 per kg of metal 5% of sale price Minor Minerals w.e.f 5% of LME 28-5-94 5% of LME 2/6/2003 1) Ornamental a) Black Granite Rs.1500-2000/ M3 Rs. 20002500/ M3 b) Other varies of dykes Rs. 1000/-per M3 c) Pink & Red granites Rs.1000-2000/ M3 d) Grey & White Granites Rs.600-1500/M3 Rs.1000/- per M3 Rs.10002000/M3 Rs.10001500/M3 2) Fuller's Earth Rs.80/- tonne Rs.150/-MT 3) Shahabad Stone Rs. 3 0/- per 10 M2 Rs.50/-10 M2 4) Limestone (Non cement) Rs.15/- tonne Rs.15/- MT 5) Ord. Building stone Rs.l0/- tonne Rs.15/- MT 6) Limeshell Rs.25/- tonne Rs. 50/- MT 7) Lime Kankar ( Non-cement) Rs.10/- tonne Rs.20/-MT 8) Ordinary sand Rs.15 - 25 tonne Rs.25/- MT 9) Bricks earth Rs.10/- tonne 10) Murrum Rs.2/-tonne Rs.5/- MT Notes: LME: London Metal Exchange, MT: Metric Tonne. ROADS AND BRIDGES Rajasthan Toll Tax Rates Categories of Vehicles Rate per vehicle 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 Car 3 3 Jeep 3 3 3 5 5 5 Mini Bus 5 5 5 10 10 10 Truck 10 10 10 15 15 15 Bus 10 10 10 15 15 15 5 5 5 10 10 10 Troll 10 10 10 15 15 15 Roller 10 10 10 15 15 15 Earth moving machine 10 10 10 15 15 15 5 5 5 10 10 10 Tractor and Trolley Small Commercial Vehicle Muli-excel vehicle Two wheeler 5 2003-04 3 5 5 10 10 10 15 15 15 NC NC NC NC NC NC 188 Annexure A.3 Constitutional Provision Related to Regulation and Development of Mines and Mineral Sector. The Seventh Schedule of the Constitution List II (State List) Entry 23 relates to regulation and development of mines and minerals; however it is subject to the provisions of Union list with respect to regulation and development. Entry 50 includes taxes on mineral rights, Entry 53 List I gives the power to Centre to regulate and develop oilfields and minerals and Entry 54 of the Union List enunciates regulation and development of mines and minerals would be under the control of the Central Government if Parliament made a law to be expedient in the public interest. Thus the Constitutional arrangements regarding the regulation of mines and minerals development are on the lines of Government India Act, 1935, except the oil fields that has been dealt in a separate entry (53) of the Union List of the Constitution. Subsequently Parliament has enacted the Mines and Minerals (Regulation and Development) Act, 1957 to provide the regulation and development of minerals under the control of the Union in public interest. This gave rise to lots of conflicts and disputes with respect to tax imposition between the States and the Central Government, therefore, the issues needs to be examined and the Supreme Court held that the jurisdiction of the State Legislature under Entry 23 is subject to limitation imposed by the latter part of the Entry. If Parliament by its law has declared that regulation and development of mines and minerals should be under the control of the Union, to the extent the jurisdiction of State Legislature is excluded. The State Legislature has no jurisdiction to pass a law in this respect. Subsequently the Supreme Court has given precedence to Parliament over States. As a result Parliament has occupied the entire field and the State Legislature lacks legislative competence and executive authority in regard to regulation and development of mines and minerals. Therefore where a law is attributable in pith and substance to entry 23 of the State list, it would not be valid as long as Parliament has occupied the field. State Governments are competent to give licenses for prospecting and granting mining leases but they can not grant or renew, prospecting licenses or mining leases without the prior permission of the Union Governments but not apply to minor minerals. By notification in the Official Gazette the State Governments may make rules for regulating grant of quarry-lease, mining-lease or other concessions in respect of minor minerals. From independence a list of amendment took place in mines and mineral sector in India. 1. The MMRD Act, 1958 (15 of 1958). 2. The Repealing and Amending Act, 1960 (58 of 1958). 3. The MMRD Amendment Act, 1972 (56 of 1972). 4. The Repealing and Amending Act, 1978 (38 of 1978). 5. The MMRD Amendment Act, 1986 (37 of 1986). 6. The MMRD Amendment Act, 1994 (25 of 1994). 7. The MMRD Amendment Act, 1999 (38 of 1999). 189 Annexure A.4 Rates of Royalty and Dead Rent for Minerals (2000-01) Rates of Royalty in Respect of Minerals at Item 1 to 10 and 12 to 38 and 40 to 51 Applicable in All States and Union Territories Except West Bengal. 1. Agate Ten percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 2. (i) Apatite Five percent of sale price on ad valorem basis (ii) Rock Phosphate 3. Asbestos (a)above 25 percent P2O5 Eleven percent of sale price on ad valorem basis (b)upto 25 percent P2O5 Five percent of sale price on ad valorem basis (a) chrysotile Seven hundred and twenty six rupees per tonne (b) amphibole Thirty five rupees per tonne 4. Barytes Five and half percent of sale price on ad valorm basis 5. Bauxite, Laterite Zero point three five percent of London Metal Exchange Aluminium metal price chargeable on the contained Aluminium metal in ore produced 6. Brown ilmenite (Leucoxene, Ilmenite, Rutile and Zircon) Two percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 7. Cadmium Ten percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 8. Calcite Fifteen percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 9. China clay/Kaolin: (including ball clay, white shale and white clay) (a) Crude Twenty one rupees per tonne (b)Processed(including washed) Seventy five rupees per tonne 10. Chromite Seven and half percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 11. Coal (including lignite) * 12. Copper Three point two percent of London Metal Exchange Copper metal price chargeable on the contained Copper metal in ore produced 13. Corundum Ten percent of sale on ad valorem basis 14. Diamond Ten percent of sale on ad valorem basis 15. Dolomite Fifty rupees per tonne 16. Felspar Ten percent of sale on ad valorem basis 17.FireClay(Including plastic,pipe,lithomargic and natural pozzolanic clay) Twelve percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 18. Flurospar Five percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 19. Garnet 20. Gold (a) abrasive Three percent of sale price on ad valorem basis (b) Gem Ten percent of sale price on ad valorem basis (a) Primary (a) One and half percent of London bullion market association price chargeable on the contained Gold metal in ore produced (b) By-product (b) Two and half percent of London bullion market association price chargeable on the by-product Gold metal actually produced 190 21. Graphite (a) with 80% or more fixed carbon Two hundred and twenty five rupees per tonne (b) with 40% or more but less than 80% fixed carbon One hundred and thirty rupees per tonne Fifty rupees per tonne (c) with less than 40% fixed carbon 22. Gypsum 23. Iron ore Twenty percent of sale price on ad valorem basis Lumps: (a) with 65% Fe content or more Twenty four rupees and fifty paise per tonne (b) with 62% Fe content or more but less than 65% Fe Fourteen rupees and fifty paise per tonne (c) with 60% Fe content or more but less than 62% Fe Ten rupees per tonne (d) less than 60% Fe content Seven rupees per tonne Fines:(including interalia, natural fines produced incidental to mining & sizing of lumpy ore) (a) with 65% Fe content or more Seventeen rupees per tonne (b) with 62% Fe content or more but less than 65% Fe Ten rupees per tonne (c) less than 62% Fe content Seven rupees per tonne Concentrates prepared by beneficiation and/or concentration of low grade ore containing 40% Fe or less Three rupees per tonne 24. Kyanite Ten percent of sale price in ad valorem basis 25. Lead Five percent of London Metal Exchange lead metal price chargeable on the contained Lead metal in ore produced 26. Limestone (a)L.D.Grade (less than 1.5% silica content Fifty rupees per tonne (b) others Forty rupees per tonne 27. Lime kankar Forty rupees per tonne 28. Lime shell Forty rupees per tonne 29. Magnesite Three percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 30. Manganese Ore (a) Ore of all grades (a) Three percent of sale price on ad valorem basis (b)Concentrates (b) One percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 31. Crude Mica, Waste and Scrap Mica Four percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 32. monazite One hundred and twenty five rupees per tonne 33. Nickel Zero point one two percent of London Metal Exchange nickel price chargeable on contained Nickel metal in ore produced 34. Ochre Twelve rupees per tonne 35. Pyrites Two percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 36. Pyophyllite Fifteen percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 37. Quartz, Silica sand, Moulding sand and Quartzite Fifteen rupees per tonne 191 38. Ruby Ten percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 39. Sand for stowing ** 40. Selenite Ten percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 41. Sillimanite Two and half percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 42. Silver (a) By-products (b)Primary silver (a) Five percent of London Metal Exchange silver metal price chargeable on by product silver metal actually produced (b) Five percent of London Metal Exchange silver metal price chargeable on the contained silver metal in ore produced 43. Slate Forty rupees per tonne 44. Talc, Steatite and Soapstone Fifteen percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 45. Tin Five percent of London Metal Exchange Tin metal price chargeable on the contained Tin metal in ore produced 46. Tungsten Twenty rupees per unit % of contained WO3 per tonne of ore and on pro rata basis 47. Uranium Five rupees for dry ore with U3O8 content of 0.05% with pro rata increase/decrease @Re.1.50 per metric tonne of ore for 0.01% increase/decrease 48. Vermiclite Three percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 49. Wollastonite Ten percent of sale price on ad valorem basis 50. Zinc Six point six percent of London Metal Exchange Zinc metal price chargeable on contained Zinc metal in ore produced 51. All other minerals not here-inbefore specified Ten percent of sale price on ad valorem basis * Rates of royalty in respect of item 11 relating to Coal Including Lignite can be revised through a separate notification by the Ministry of Coal. ** Rates of royalty in respect of item 39 relating to Sand for Stowing can be revised through a separate notification by the Ministry of Coal. Note: The rates of royalty for the state of West Bengal in respect of the minerals except item 11 shall remain same as specified in the notification of Govt of India in 1987. Note: The Second Schedule was amended earlier vide notification numbers:1. GSR No. 175(E) dated 31st March, 1975. 2. GSR No. 407(E) dated 14th July, 1975. 3. GSR No. 584(E) dated 13th December, 1975. 4. GSR No. 321(E) dated 12th June, 1978. 5. GSR No. 2(E) dated 1st January, 1979. 6. GSR No. 67(E) dated 13th February, 1979. 7. GSR No. 63(E) dated 12th February, 1981. 8. GSR No. 449(E) dated 23rd July, 1981. 9. GSR No. 458(E) dated 5th May, 1987. 192 10. GSR No. 856(E) dated 14th October, 1987. 11. GSR No. 516(E) dated 1st August, 1991. 12. GSR No. 100(E) dated 17th February, 1992. 13. GSR No. 748(E) dated 11th October, 1994. 14. GSR No. 27(E) dated 13th January, 1995. 15. GSR No. 214(E) dated 11th April, 1997. Rates of Dead Rent (Applicable for All States and Union Territories except the State of West Bengal) (Rates of Dead Rent in Rupees per hectare per annum) Item Category of The mining lease Number 1st year of the 2nd to 5th year of the 6th to 10th year of the 11th year of the lease and lease lease lease onwards (a) Lease area upto 50 hectares Nil 70 140 200 (b) Lease area above 50 hectares but Nil 100 200 280 Nil 140 230 350 not exceeding 100 hectares (c) Lease area above 100 hectares Source: - Ministry of Mines, Government of India, 2000. (1) The rates of dead rent applicable to the leases other than those obtained for supply of raw material to the industry owned by the concerned lessee. (2) In the case of lease obtained for the supply of raw materials for the industry owned by the concerned lessee, the rates of dead rent would be applicable as given in respect of item number (a) above, irrespective of the lease area and the value of the mineral. (3) One and half times the rates specified in item numbers (a), (b) and (c) above in case of leases granted for medium value minerals. (4) Two times the rates specified in item numbers (a), (b) and (c) above in case of leases granted for high value minerals. Note: For the purpose of this notification:(1) (a) “High value minerals” means gold, silver, diamond, ruby, sapphire, emerald and all other gemstones (precious, semi-precious stones), copper, lead, zinc, asbestos (chrysotile variety), corundum, mica. (b) “Medium value minerals” means agate, chromite, manganese ore, sillimanite, vermiculite, magnesite, wollastonite, perlite, diaspore, apatite and rock phosphate, fluorspar, barites. (c) “Low value minerals” means minerals other than high value minerals and medium value minerals. (2) The rates of dead rent for the state of West Bengal shall remain the same as specified in the notification of Govt of India in 1987. Note: The Third Schedule was amended earlier vide notification numbers:1. GSR No. 458(E) dated 5th May, 1987. 2. GSR No. 856(E) dated 14th October, 1987. 3. GSR No. 214(E) dated 11th April, 1997. 193 APPENDIXES STATISTICAL TABLES ……. Tables Prepared from State Budget Documents Table No. Page No. Title of Table A Revenue Receipts Tables for 15 Major states Budget Data (1993-96 and 2001-04) 200-218 1 Revenue from Total Public Works (Rs. in 000’) 200 1a Revenue from Hire Charges(102) and Centage of Recovery Charges(103) (Rs. in 000’) 200 1b Revenue from Public Works -(102+103) (Rs. in 000’) 201 2 Revenue from Education, Sport, Art and Culture (Rs. in 000’) 201 2a Revenue from General Education (Rs. in 000’) 202 2b Revenue from Technical Education (Rs. in 000’) 202 2c Revenue from Art and Culture (Rs. In 000’) 203 203 2d Revenue from Education, Sports, Art & Culture - (Sports & Youth Services + Art & Culture) (Rs. in 000’) 2e Revenue from Sports and Youth Services (Rs. in 000’) 204 2f Revenue from Elementary Education (Rs. in 000’) 204 2g Revenue from Secondary Education (Rs. in 000’) 205 2h Revenue from University and Higher Education (Rs. in 000’) 205 2i Revenue from Adult Education (Rs. In 000’) 206 3 Revenue from Medical and Public Health (Rs. in 000’) 206 3a Revenue from Urban Health Services (Rs. in 000’) 207 3b Revenue from Rural Health Services (Rs. in 000’) 207 3c Revenue from Medical Education, Training and Research (Rs. in 000’) 208 3d Revenue from Public Health (Rs. in 000’) 208 3e Revenue from General Medical service (Rs. in 000’) 209 4 Revenue from Water Supply and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) 209 4a Revenue from Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) 210 4b Revenue from Sewage and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) 210 4c Revenue from Rural Water Supply (Rs. In 000’) 211 4d Revenue from Urban Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) 211 5 Revenue from Forestry and Wildlife (Rs. in 000’) 212 5a Revenue from Total Forestry (Rs. in 000’) 212 5b Revenue from Total Environmental Forestry and Wildlife (Rs. in 000’) 213 5c Revenue from Sale of Forest Products (Rs. in 000’) 213 5d Revenue from Total Environmental Forestry and Wildlife (Rs. in 000’) 214 195 6 Revenue from Major and Medium Irrigation (Rs. in 000’) 214 7 Revenue from Minor Irrigation (Rs. in 000’) 215 7a Revenue from Total Surface Water (Rs. In 000’) 215 7b Revenue from Total Ground Water (Rs. In 000’) 216 7c Revenue from Total Water Tanks (Rs. in 000’) 216 7d Revenue from Revenue from Total Lift Irrigation (Rs. in 000’) 217 8 Revenue from Industries (Rs. in 000’) 217 9 Revenue from Non Ferrous and Metallurgical Industries (Rs. in 000’) 218 10 Revenue from Roads and Bridges (Rs. in 000’) 218 219-252 B Revenue Expenditure Tables for 15 Major States Budget Data (1993-96 and 200104) 1 Revenue Expenditure on Public Works (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 219 Revenue Expenditure on Public Works (Machinery & Equipment &Maintenance & Repairs) (Rs. in 000’) 219 2 Public Works (excluding Machinery & Equipment and Maintenance & Repairs) (Rs. in 000’) 220 3 4 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu., Sports, Art & Culture (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 220 5 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 221 6 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 221 7 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 222 8 Revenue Expenditure on Technical Edu (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 222 9 Revenue Expenditure on Technical Edu (Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 223 10 Revenue Expenditure on Technical Edu (excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 223 11 Revenue Expenditure on Sports & Youth Services (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 224 12 Revenue Expenditure on Sports & Youth Services (Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 224 13 Revenue Expenditure on Sports & Youth Services (excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 225 14 Revenue Expenditure on Art & Culture (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 225 15 Revenue Expenditure on Art & Culture (Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 226 16 Revenue Expenditure on Art & Culture (excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 226 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu, Sports, Art & Culture [excl. Sports + Art & Culture] (Rs. in 000’) 227 17 18 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Elementary Edu: TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 227 19 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Elementary Edu: Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 228 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Elementary Edu: excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 228 20 196 21 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Secondary Edu: TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 229 22 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Secondary Edu: Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 229 230 23 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Secondary Edu: excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 24 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Uni. & Higher Edu: TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 230 25 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Uni. & Higher Edu: Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 231 231 26 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Uni. & Higher Edu: excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 27 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Adult Edu: TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 232 28 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Adult Edu: Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 232 29 Revenue Expenditure on General Edu (Adult Edu: excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) 233 30 Revenue Expenditure on Total Medical And Public Health (Rs. in 000’) 233 31 Revenue Expenditure on Total Urban Health Services (Rs. in 000’) 234 32 Revenue Expenditure on Urban Health Services Allopathy (Rs. in 000’) 234 33 Revenue Expenditure on Urban Health Services Other Systems (Rs. in 000’) 235 Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Urban Health Services Other Systems (Rs. in 000’) 235 34 236 35 Revenue Expenditure on Urban Health Services Other Systems - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) 36 Revenue Expenditure on Total Rural Health Services (Rs. in 000’) 236 37 Revenue Expenditure on Rural Health Services Allopathy (Rs. in 000’) 237 38 Revenue Expenditure on Rural Health Services Other Systems (Rs. in 000’) 237 39 Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Rural Health Services (Rs. in 000’) 238 40 Revenue Expenditure on Rural Health Services - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) 238 41 Revenue Expenditure on Medical Education, Training and Research (Rs. in 000’) 239 42 Revenue Expenditure on Public Health (Rs. in 000’) 239 43 Revenue Expenditure on Total Water Supply and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) 240 44 Revenue Expenditure on Total Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) 240 45 Revenue Expenditure on Total Sewage and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) 241 46 Revenue Expenditure on Total Urban Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) 241 47 Revenue Expenditure on Total Rural Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) 242 48 Revenue Expenditure on Total Assistance to Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) 242 49 Revenue Expenditure on Water Supply - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) 243 50 Revenue Expenditure on Total Assistance To Sewage and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) 243 51 Revenue Expenditure on Sewage and Sanitation - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) 244 197 52 Revenue Expenditure on Total Forestry and Wildlife (Rs. in 000’) 244 53 Revenue Expenditure on Total Forestry (Rs. in 000’) 245 54 Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Forestry (Rs. in 000’) 245 55 Revenue Expenditure on Forestry - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) 246 56 Revenue Expenditure on Environmental Forestry (Rs. in 000’) 246 57 Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Environmental Forestry (Rs. in 000’) 247 58 Revenue Expenditure on Environmental Forestry - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) 247 59 Revenue Expenditure on Total Minor Irrigation (Rs. in 000’) 248 60 Revenue Expenditure on Surface Water (Rs. in 000’) 248 61 Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Surface Water (Rs. in 000’) 249 62 Revenue Expenditure on Ground Water (Rs. in 000’) 249 63 Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Ground Water (Rs. in 000’) 250 64 Revenue Expenditure on Water Tanks (Rs. in 000’) 250 65 Revenue Expenditure on Industries (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 251 Revenue Expenditure on Non Ferrous Mining & Metallurgical Industries (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 251 66 67 Revenue Expenditure on Roads & Bridges (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) 252 Tables Prepared from RBI Data Source Table No. Page No. Title of the Table C Tables from RBI Revenue Receipts from 1993-94 to 2003-04 253-272 1 Total State Own Revenue (Tax +Non-tax) (in Rs. Lakh) 253 2 States’ Own Non-Tax Revenue (in Rs. Lakh) 254 3 Interest Payments (in Rs. Lakh) 255 4 Dividends and Profits (in Rs. Lakh) 256 5 Revenue from General Services (in Rs. Lakh) 257 6 Revenue from Social Services (in Rs. Lakh) 258 7 Revenue from Education, Sports, Art and Culture (in Rs. Lakh) 259 8 Revenue from Medical, Public Health and Family Welfare (in Rs. Lakh) 260 9 Revenue from Housing (in Rs. Lakh) 261 10 Revenue from Urban Development (in Rs. Lakh) 262 11 Revenue from Water Supply and Sanitation (in Rs. Lakh) 263 198 12 Revenue from Economic Services (in Rs. Lakh) 264 13 Revenue from Forestry and Wildlife (in Rs. Lakh) 265 14 Revenue from Major and Medium Irrigation projects (in Rs. Lakh) 266 15 Revenue from Minor Irrigations (in Rs. Lakh) 267 16 Revenue from Power (in Rs. Lakh) 268 17 Revenue from Petroleum (in Rs. Lakh) 269 18 Revenue from Village and Small Industries (in Rs. Lakh) 270 19 Revenue from Industries (in Rs. Lakh) 271 20 Revenue from Road Transport (in Rs. Lakh) 272 D Tables from RBI Revenue Expenditure from 1993-94 to 2003-04 273-282 1 Revenue Expenditure on Social Services (Rs. in lakh) 273 2 Revenue Expenditure on Education, Sports, Art and Culture (Rs. in lakh) 273 Revenue Expenditure on Medical and Public Health and Family Welfare (Rs. in lakh) 274 3 4 Revenue Expenditure on Water supply and Sanitation (Rs. in lakh) 274 5 Revenue Expenditure on Housing (Rs. in lakh) 275 6 Revenue Expenditure on Urban development (Rs. in lakh) 275 7 Revenue Expenditure on Labour and Labour Welfare (Rs. in lakh) 276 8 Revenue Expenditure on Social Security and Welfare (Rs. in lakh) 276 9 Revenue Expenditure on Economic Services (Rs. in lakh) 277 10 Revenue Expenditure on Crop Husbandry (Rs. in lakh) 277 11 Revenue Expenditure on Animal Husbandry (Rs. in lakh) 278 12 Revenue Expenditure on Fisheries (Rs. in lakh) 278 13 Revenue Expenditure on Forestry and Wild Life (Rs. in lakh) 279 14 Revenue Expenditure on Co-operation (Rs. in lakh) 279 15 Revenue Expenditure on Major and Medium Irrigation (Rs. in lakh) 280 16 Revenue Expenditure on Minor Irrigation (Rs. in lakh) 280 17 Revenue Expenditure on Power (Rs. in lakh) 281 18 Revenue Expenditure on Village and Small Industries (Rs. in lakh) 281 19 Revenue Expenditure on Industries (Rs. in lakh) 282 20 Revenue Expenditure on Roads and Bridges (Rs. in lakh) 282 199 Table 1: Revenue from Total Public Works (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 60451 64786 66990 48027 64965 Bihar 5740 7109 6022 7846 11080 Goa 6910 5775 8726 12029 9466 Gujrat 100706 92704 88216 134916 117209 Haryana 25118 25665 21128 62101 39795 Karnataka 73664 87120 62187 145290 111038 Kerala 13184 15718 17720 15631 21464 Madhya Pr. 73774 76242 103686 67524 85659 Maharashtra 389582 457384 452223 627125 543104 Orissa 50769 76091 75455 139875 136937 Punjab 49992 62561 47345 78311 110925 Rajasthan 107798 123036 179082 174908 196860 Tamil Nadu 43812 42486 47864 87337 87317 Uttar Pr. 149214 137889 258488 146591 252638 West Bengal 42983 40683 64558 55200 47752 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 71056 11483 14060 185301 32141 121224 28977 90938 652562 150553 101681 164510 118205 199199 63943 Table 1a: Revenue from Hire Charges (102) and Centage of Recovery Charges (103) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 29374 22760 23957 3899 2695 462 Bihar 0 0 0 0 0 0 Goa 2402 1995 2648 1128 1885 3647 Gujrat 32039 25411 24588 9847 14278 20683 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 2392 0 3232 2421 7343 3123 Kerala 150 332 137 0 0 54 Madhya Pr. 31497 34813 25119 7671 11308 24342 Maharashtra 216208 238850 220624 262896 238326 289661 Orissa 0 0 7846 21639 13544 15975 Punjab 40574 51481 33110 44002 48759 44931 Rajasthan 75759 78816 96096 107018 129597 96530 Tamil Nadu 13600 9858 7260 9278 12985 8299 Uttar Pr. 14632 14426 30219 6226 127682 28778 West Bengal 2672 4128 10050 15876 9254 7263 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 200 Table 1b: Revenue from Public Works -(102+103) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 31077 42026 43033 44127 62270 Bihar 5740 7109 6022 7846 11080 Goa 4508 3780 6078 10900 7580 Gujrat 68667 67293 63628 125069 102931 Haryana 25118 25665 21128 62101 39795 Karnataka 71272 87120 58955 142869 103695 Kerala 13034 15386 17583 15631 21464 Madhya Pr. 42278 41430 78567 59852 74352 Maharashtra 173374 218534 231599 364229 304778 Orissa 50769 76091 67609 118236 123393 Punjab 9418 11080 14235 34309 62166 Rajasthan 32039 44220 82986 67890 67263 Tamil Nadu 30211 32629 40605 78059 74331 Uttar Pr. 134583 123463 228269 140365 124956 West Bengal 40311 36554 54509 39324 38498 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 70594 11483 10413 164618 32141 118101 28923 66596 362901 134578 56750 67980 109906 170421 56679 Table 2: Revenue from Education, Sport, Art and Culture (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 300540 227148 223374 924474 Bihar 28142 19481 29880 549569 Goa 3841 4401 9663 20793 Gujrat 180905 153850 197355 393487 Haryana 120735 123562 135366 214018 Karnataka 176683 157910 150297 355595 Kerala 217699 283175 290799 535631 Madhya Pr. 50050 63274 74667 129895 Maharashtra 232306 285254 314049 330283 Orissa 95193 112301 115821 249791 Punjab 57113 60265 67323 138783 Rajasthan 38644 67078 119530 342680 Tamil Nadu 248179 295533 296836 657883 Uttar Pr. 299391 412346 493808 1376635 West Bengal 44025 60542 137806 396138 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 1476653 83557 31702 675045 281317 433106 634095 103862 583266 243055 143920 173284 894959 2553486 172816 2003-04 7 712148 41095 115110 636624 326614 300702 818627 90766 661211 120020 212977 788114 1225765 2276789 211969 201 Table 2a: Revenue from General Education (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 281856 213171 206716 654452 Bihar 0 0 8414 547721 Goa 1793 1491 1527 4263 Gujrat 153478 131222 166713 302744 Haryana 115877 116903 133793 161317 Karnataka 111127 124795 116133 250348 Kerala 188336 241408 234677 367522 Madhya Pr. 46735 54604 62108 123135 Maharashtra 144762 174134 184995 179577 Orissa 90860 102508 108002 235748 Punjab 52888 52916 60635 106034 Rajasthan 33640 60247 108941 295335 Tamil Nadu 210246 249165 234912 479991 Uttar Pr. 294856 407105 481244 1301178 West Bengal 41014 52015 128801 357370 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 489494 73865 8478 606178 215152 366654 501708 92407 397904 231497 109662 131709 698432 2356367 146602 2003-04 7 516529 39750 88088 565011 254188 223661 637583 81614 491523 97675 150339 735532 917898 0 163120 Table 2b: Revenue from Technical Education (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 10407 11898 14937 26480 Bihar 0 0 0 862 Goa 1797 2582 3797 14858 Gujrat 12760 15142 15675 14143 Haryana 905 5866 0 52601 Karnataka 46639 12589 11592 90488 Kerala 22823 31997 33220 145394 Madhya Pr. 1660 6492 6891 5753 Maharashtra 54296 72589 90524 128296 Orissa 3775 5865 6711 11103 Punjab 2228 4187 4567 28204 Rajasthan 2347 3137 3904 10858 Tamil Nadu 33568 36144 52096 152976 Uttar Pr. 2561 4086 4011 61707 West Bengal 617 1562 1579 11770 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 30774 9153 21046 10647 65910 54672 101942 9890 145806 10050 30585 9281 155929 197120 7042 2003-04 7 77863 376 24449 16408 68850 65170 153084 4720 153756 1873 55703 12893 259941 2276789 13154 202 Table 2c: Revenue from Art and Culture (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 1825 1827 1523 231953 Bihar 52 44 61 514 Goa 242 261 290 1244 Gujrat 8978 4955 13385 72357 Haryana 1845 793 1573 6 Karnataka 13335 12619 19125 4579 Kerala 6139 8146 10495 16277 Madhya Pr. 1132 1282 1664 1007 Maharashtra 31401 35229 31742 13079 Orissa 558 3928 653 2940 Punjab 1066 868 1455 2695 Rajasthan 2657 3694 6685 34972 Tamil Nadu 2331 2364 2794 9635 Uttar Pr. 477 422 2486 11950 West Bengal 388 1139 824 6423 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 954416 297 1438 55788 21 3978 20997 269 22638 1508 1797 31763 25410 0 5696 2003-04 7 14292 704 1527 48652 477 8479 24797 4361 12661 310 3598 39216 28344 0 12905 Table 2d: Revenue from Education, Sports, Art & Culture - (Sports & Youth Services + Art & Culture) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 292263 225069 221653 680932 520268 594392 Bihar 0 0 8414 548583 83018 40126 Goa 3590 4073 5324 19121 29524 112537 Gujrat 166238 146364 182388 316887 616825 581419 Haryana 116782 122769 133793 213919 281062 323038 Karnataka 157766 137384 127725 340836 421326 288831 Kerala 211158 273405 267897 512915 603650 790667 Madhya Pr. 48395 61096 69000 128888 102296 86334 Maharashtra 21048 34058 51994 105886 106250 137824 Orissa 94635 108373 114713 246851 241547 99548 Punjab 55117 57103 65203 134238 140247 206042 Rajasthan 35987 63384 112845 306193 140990 748425 Tamil Nadu 243815 285309 287008 632967 854361 1177839 Uttar Pr. 297417 411191 485255 1362885 2553486 2276789 West Bengal 41631 53577 130380 369140 153644 176274 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 203 Table 2e: Revenue from Sports and Youth Services (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 6452 253 198 11589 Bihar 28090 19437 21405 473 Goa 10 67 4049 428 Gujrat 5689 2531 1582 4243 Haryana 2108 0 0 94 Karnataka 5582 7907 3447 10180 Kerala 402 1624 12407 6439 Madhya Pr. 523 896 4003 0 Maharashtra 1847 3302 6788 9331 Orissa 0 0 455 0 Punjab 931 2295 665 1851 Rajasthan 0 0 0 1515 Tamil Nadu 2033 7860 7034 15281 Uttar Pr. 1498 733 6068 1801 West Bengal 2007 5827 6602 20575 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 1969 243 739 2432 234 7802 9447 1297 16918 0 1875 531 15188 0 13476 2003-04 7 103464 265 1046 6553 3099 3392 3163 71 3271 20162 3337 473 19582 0 22790 Table 2f: Revenue from Elementary Education (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 46956 38380 38315 85627 Bihar 0 0 0 9523 Goa 36 5 19 28 Gujrat 34094 27035 39502 141498 Haryana 95968 92568 10885 154904 Karnataka 3674 5999 854 2327 Kerala 2953 4430 4398 10062 Madhya Pr. 0 3869 0 0 Maharashtra 17930 22458 57662 41442 Orissa 57413 1230 62986 139982 Punjab 4671 4457 6340 31455 Rajasthan 12832 18117 50458 213970 Tamil Nadu 315 117 363 11838 Uttar Pr. 11025 14471 27135 10295 West Bengal 161 741 262 3207 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 57845 9562 231 428759 144907 -1 8349 1210 123306 176203 19728 51034 10728 0 1317 2003-04 7 161951 31236 492 199224 176778 223661 9751 1742 191998 19606 21921 638743 88802 0 2025 204 Table 2g: Revenue from Secondary Education (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 210971 148578 146128 160462 Bihar 0 0 8414 3492 Goa 59 109 126 76 Gujrat 29570 29750 39954 50026 Haryana 14671 21533 108992 3513 Karnataka 95137 109569 115279 248021 Kerala 146422 180814 150960 267116 Madhya Pr. 4512 126 6291 6340 Maharashtra 12664 18538 7967 9988 Orissa 1277 151 901 18708 Punjab 33748 37084 39639 56720 Rajasthan 16602 35484 40358 66066 Tamil Nadu 179748 200879 197716 382457 Uttar Pr. 199904 390061 450248 765706 West Bengal 3176 1347 2553 3359 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 331467 5819 4063 86630 58211 366655 349074 10000 7235 0 67180 65343 604151 810679 983 2003-04 7 340458 6536 20472 114502 66174 0 390719 13664 54340 83 58056 67703 715525 0 7129 Table 2h: Revenue from University and Higher Education (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 21489 21049 16167 29768 Bihar 0 0 0 416616 Goa 703 976 1047 3619 Gujrat 62574 55775 57647 60393 Haryana 5385 2182 14198 3239 Karnataka 11793 8648 0 0 Kerala 38990 56235 79320 90099 Madhya Pr. 12514 12483 14851 46639 Maharashtra 12801 14230 14707 20136 Orissa 9437 2041 9846 20186 Punjab 9543 8053 10817 15498 Rajasthan 3599 5873 15719 14260 Tamil Nadu 23285 46532 33205 76285 Uttar Pr. 83927 2562 3808 51 West Bengal 4359 4897 5178 5181 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 37167 26476 3563 55667 10470 0 143636 19496 21803 8768 19265 13738 68650 0 4596 2003-04 7 47360 1781 66813 113662 11193 0 236815 8577 20333 349 62980 20949 100430 0 6556 205 Table 2i: Revenue from Adult Education (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 0 6 0 13 3 Bihar 0 0 0 12532 190 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 0 0 0 0 0 Haryana 0 807 0 308 1564 Karnataka 523 579 0 0 0 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 0 0 0 0 2 Maharashtra 965 509 501 97 227 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 160 231 1 62 168 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 486 61 359 4383 5393 Uttar Pr. 0 11 41 6065 1721 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 0 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 3: Revenue from Medical and Public Health (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 192311 146661 135074 485265 380548 Bihar 96928 56046 91673 165033 139191 Goa 14939 15676 21931 46720 69379 Gujrat 317710 275335 278988 472607 390175 Haryana 124526 86232 102390 283184 283767 Karnataka 223663 228133 213568 591763 563775 Kerala 153087 113799 235258 198459 281591 Madhya Pr. 83371 75352 87252 161433 203557 Maharashtra 572732 628839 562401 1097763 958894 Orissa 49967 46069 34591 101497 112411 Punjab 207807 208723 112735 290000 412957 Rajasthan 152491 99264 164851 245717 223958 Tamil Nadu 273170 282245 336483 653242 830671 Uttar Pr. 147697 189444 137903 311437 414359 West Bengal 427279 274236 223145 456304 486197 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 40 0 0 0 200 0 0 0 123 0 0 0 4291 0 0 2003-04 7 292987 119670 73016 415981 319635 317805 276116 109760 915300 75108 414382 162796 601091 426906 477069 206 Table 3a: Revenue from Urban Health Services (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 163823 126791 104334 401861 262415 Bihar 31095 15752 45020 32037 11874 Goa 13975 13092 16043 28888 46337 Gujrat 290870 234763 212521 347661 243940 Haryana 123006 83949 90291 230445 228652 Karnataka 219883 222975 208063 537095 506029 Kerala 138437 91029 212888 135607 191276 Madhya Pr. 80388 71754 80920 50179 6005 Maharashtra 504548 535876 449839 830381 642501 Orissa 41802 39188 26954 56941 60360 Punjab 195900 193527 94409 168764 371642 Rajasthan 150421 98604 163404 169273 163111 Tamil Nadu 252015 244195 305504 540716 707549 Uttar Pr. 35665 173592 106063 309888 414359 West Bengal 425839 273690 221195 452577 480000 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 3b: Revenue from Rural Health Services (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 Bihar 51448 30142 34900 757 1176 Goa 334 483 658 2171 2401 Gujrat 214 91 24 9334 5632 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 0 89 150 1562 0 Kerala 697 777 753 1843 2317 Madhya Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 Maharashtra 4310 2780 6489 3600 13255 Orissa 4298 3140 4400 11500 17058 Punjab 381 2284 6930 45585 3026 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 0 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 215243 31075 47945 267190 238999 224363 188013 8275 465148 35353 333561 103397 512228 426906 450300 2003-04 7 0 0 3101 4488 450 774 3051 37 44190 231 9081 0 0 0 0 207 Table 3c: Revenue from Medical Education, Training and Research (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 8814 11177 15721 37170 41634 38541 Bihar 8655 5200 6148 1042 4158 11652 Goa 380 983 2403 7942 12426 13505 Gujrat 2029 6641 3851 20451 18650 14862 Haryana 146 115 112 49001 51276 76673 Karnataka 2334 1925 2050 18350 22258 64754 Kerala 7301 12920 11596 21219 41364 50375 Madhya Pr. 38 84 79 818 568 25973 Maharashtra 27572 49365 49967 108589 103691 102419 Orissa 583 1933 1560 10118 10545 0 Punjab 2183 3270 3958 1166 26148 59262 Rajasthan 1118 147 284 11395 10665 19121 Tamil Nadu 7172 13068 13182 23543 25963 32641 Uttar Pr. 427 901 352 70 0 0 West Bengal 909 135 1842 3466 5722 15234 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 3d: Revenue from Public Health (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 6374 6321 6015 39606 72419 Bihar 5520 4753 5386 8634 5148 Goa 252 1131 2845 7590 8315 Gujrat 4046 4349 5625 33534 83227 Haryana 1374 2168 11987 3737 3839 Karnataka 1446 3144 3305 34756 35488 Kerala 2442 2373 2589 27253 29868 Madhya Pr. 2945 3515 6253 110436 196984 Maharashtra 36302 40818 56106 155193 199447 Orissa 3284 1808 1677 22938 24448 Punjab 1944 2146 5751 474 1362 Rajasthan 952 513 1163 65049 50182 Tamil Nadu 13984 24981 17797 88983 97158 Uttar Pr. 111605 14950 31487 1479 0 West Bengal 531 411 108 261 475 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 34162 16204 8500 91987 3513 27914 16941 75412 303543 39524 5843 40278 56222 0 11535 208 Table 3e: Revenue from General Medical service (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 13300 2372 9004 6629 Bihar 210 199 218 122562 Goa -2 -14 -17 130 Gujrat 20551 29491 56967 61628 Haryana 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 Kerala 4210 6700 7432 12537 Madhya Pr. 0 0 0 0 Maharashtra 0 0 0 0 Orissa 0 0 0 0 Punjab 7399 7497 1687 74010 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 4081 116834 -100 38726 0 0 16766 0 0 0 10779 0 0 0 0 2003-04 7 5041 60739 -35 37454 0 0 17736 63 0 0 6635 0 0 0 0 Table 4: Revenue from Water Supply and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 39895 48235 51738 90944 Bihar 16524 9869 13380 3579 Goa 106817 112655 155043 531344 Gujrat 564 5055 6251 4962 Haryana 80982 109245 130540 287037 Karnataka 6979 19019 15964 18636 Kerala 42 106 2545 12776 Madhya Pr. 151445 131253 94476 115126 Maharashtra 107023 111815 34442 50882 Orissa 56878 59431 63992 189588 Punjab 62113 77995 85579 153109 Rajasthan 556830 654806 757623 1398262 Tamil Nadu 24973 40165 23673 88476 Uttar Pr. 798 871 829 1582 West Bengal 7714 11840 15236 36706 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 163524 2576 557115 12226 358175 11521 26843 193853 27046 232902 219677 1430039 82584 64 30142 2003-04 7 61746 3243 546647 10145 373117 6093 27427 196395 104184 241626 268068 1462966 67451 29032 63005 209 Table 4a: Revenue from Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 30688 133 15102 47967 163516 Bihar 1790 9869 2452 3579 2576 Goa 103515 110615 152972 524689 552007 Gujrat 564 5055 6251 4962 12226 Haryana 80542 108187 129044 266159 342397 Karnataka 6979 19019 15964 18636 11521 Kerala 0 61 2501 12776 26843 Madhya Pr. 132772 122332 74149 87986 153280 Maharashtra 104632 103567 33778 30231 22803 Orissa 45556 59431 63992 189588 199644 Punjab 62113 77995 85579 153109 219677 Rajasthan 501897 564424 647166 1253136 1292763 Tamil Nadu 24970 40154 23243 88458 82584 Uttar Pr. 798 871 829 1582 64 West Bengal 7710 11825 15068 36692 30092 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 4b: Revenue from Sewage and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 9207 48103 36636 42977 8 Bihar 14734 0 10929 0 0 Goa 3302 2040 2071 6655 5108 Gujrat 0 0 0 0 0 Haryana 440 1059 1496 20878 15778 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 0 Kerala 41 45 45 0 0 Madhya Pr. 18673 8921 20327 27140 40573 Maharashtra 2391 8248 664 20757 4243 Orissa 11322 0 0 0 33258 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 54933 90382 110457 145126 137276 Tamil Nadu 3 11 431 17 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 4 15 169 14 51 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 54585 3243 504103 10145 357875 6093 99 177753 38422 241560 268068 1308773 67451 29032 62663 2003-04 7 7161 0 42544 0 15242 0 27328 18642 65762 66 0 154193 0 0 341 210 Table 4c: Revenue from Rural Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 30522 5 14905 44381 65227 Bihar 0 0 0 1494 1639 Goa 19318 15678 20667 120517 129787 Gujrat 222 435 0 0 672 Haryana 579 962 488 29963 33090 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 0 Kerala 0 1 0 0 1 Madhya Pr. 0 0 0 4 4306 Maharashtra 143 1199 0 2642 466 Orissa 705 58664 862 3516 3978 Punjab 29481 37706 38866 112163 168669 Rajasthan 93698 103654 111819 234170 240124 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 2 7 16 2 1 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 4d: Revenue from Urban Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 71 106 197 40 2 Bihar 842 8279 0 75 705 Goa 78792 91708 120735 378297 400283 Gujrat 0 0 0 0 1645 Haryana 12653 17528 30770 161911 148038 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 0 Kerala 0 0 0 9 14471 Madhya Pr. 94973 71760 40609 60511 127449 Maharashtra 250 448 2274 63 0 Orissa 44834 767 54307 156637 195666 Punjab 3758 5448 11261 14543 18003 Rajasthan 405259 456741 532257 1011753 1035806 Tamil Nadu 16135 38536 22707 2639 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 0 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 54585 543 136990 7920 56505 0 23 48 1757 4296 204996 253509 0 0 2 2003-04 7 0 118 341311 243 172286 0 22 155002 40 183014 29389 1042201 0 0 0 211 Table 5: Revenue from Forestry and Wildlife (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 704390 1028611 1447604 462041 710972 Bihar 389227 369055 273376 170704 100366 Goa 11482 13887 13882 11793 7305 Gujrat 152339 167516 147232 283399 324857 Haryana 118482 133603 178007 245332 289682 Karnataka 919799 950793 1060910 1009008 1015229 Kerala 1029584 1368849 1607654 1137026 1495799 Madhya Pr. 4921154 5231477 5738382 3064501 4973028 Maharashtra 1360464 1927965 1439812 1341420 1045786 Orissa 994715 1188017 682624 879496 970416 Punjab 52826 51469 68547 151164 158154 Rajasthan 112947 136464 135979 448245 416302 Tamil Nadu 552670 648061 579660 970398 1574363 Uttar Pr. 1211593 818935 1010808 683114 862714 West Bengal 324433 446093 442698 267185 565222 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 5a: Revenue from Total Forestry (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 703728 1028463 1440481 462106 710825 Bihar 389227 369055 273376 134274 94653 Goa 11482 13887 13882 11793 7305 Gujrat 151177 166452 145657 282326 320430 Haryana 118177 133093 177632 245332 289682 Karnataka 917310 947766 1057331 1000913 1006936 Kerala 1029584 1368849 1607654 1137026 1495799 Madhya Pr. 4921154 5231477 5738382 3064501 4973028 Maharashtra 1250157 1920929 1426246 1341816 1031186 Orissa 993260 1183652 678901 871722 961614 Punjab 52826 51469 68547 151164 158154 Rajasthan 109884 132725 130641 426597 401904 Tamil Nadu 552670 648061 579131 970398 1574363 Uttar Pr. 1087761 812113 1003269 683114 862714 West Bengal 319449 441794 439399 245708 548776 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 929466 62884 18057 498567 254798 1806563 1871833 4967478 863250 486372 80834 395329 902127 609607 459744 2003-04 7 928994 37664 18057 490874 254796 1797745 1871833 4967478 847083 478612 80834 358573 902127 609607 436875 212 Table 5b: Revenue from Other Sources (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 21384 162064 153739 126156 194139 Bihar 77641 94453 38935 76202 63719 Goa 889 1046 10827 6127 6309 Gujrat 19187 21282 27973 58643 49822 Haryana 42449 57115 64618 234060 257385 Karnataka 80095 95770 123830 281935 257733 Kerala 31132 43867 59760 60776 42675 Madhya Pr. 4597834 4888188 5392798 2697504 4528005 Maharashtra 298039 527820 240462 107569 75102 Orissa 13975 98853 24985 41664 100281 Punjab 7929 11365 12659 23331 105353 Rajasthan 38358 45235 53404 156591 170189 Tamil Nadu 375720 425713 410824 269180 315220 Uttar Pr. 142609 157033 175604 683114 862714 West Bengal 54656 56338 88866 56882 122733 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 5c: Revenue from Sale of Forest Products (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 682344 866400 1286742 335950 516686 Bihar 311586 274602 234442 58072 30934 Goa 10592 12841 3056 5666 996 Gujrat 131989 145170 117684 223684 270608 Haryana 75728 75978 113014 11272 32297 Karnataka 837215 851996 933501 718978 749203 Kerala 998453 1324982 1547894 1076250 1453124 Madhya Pr. 323320 343289 345584 366997 444996 Maharashtra 952118 1393109 1185784 1234247 956084 Orissa 979285 1084799 653916 830058 861333 Punjab 44897 40104 55888 127833 52801 Rajasthan 71526 87490 77237 270006 231715 Tamil Nadu 176950 222348 168308 701218 1259143 Uttar Pr. 945152 655080 827665 0 0 West Bengal 264793 385456 350533 188826 426043 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 240180 22659 15992 107753 119613 1170860 70650 4564100 69365 105122 29556 123433 440193 609607 69516 2003-04 7 688814 15005 2065 383121 135183 626885 1801183 403378 777718 373490 51278 235140 461934 0 367358 213 Table 5d: Revenue from Total Environmental Forestry and Wildlife (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 662 148 7124 -65 148 472 Bihar 0 0 0 36430 5713 25220 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 1163 1064 1575 1073 4427 7693 Haryana 306 510 375 0 0 2 Karnataka 2489 3027 3579 8095 8293 8818 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 0 Maharashtra 110307 7036 13566 -396 14600 16167 Orissa 1455 4365 3723 7774 8802 7760 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 3063 3739 5338 21648 14398 36756 Tamil Nadu 0 0 528 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 123832 6822 7539 0 0 0 West Bengal 4983 4299 3299 21477 16447 22870 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 6: Revenue from Major and Medium Irrigation (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 767947 1038048 946123 102671 Bihar 180238 161337 308012 155790 Goa 1774 8478 4709 136961 Gujrat 309868 425904 372244 1320860 Haryana 203822 191920 210025 685064 Karnataka 135517 131934 169287 205641 Kerala 23557 17936 26630 29933 Madhya Pr. 232412 401943 364856 271296 Maharashtra 782886 709854 770174 860345 Orissa 54989 49293 111864 165342 Punjab 164121 314564 301415 163332 Rajasthan 199235 210938 214423 184297 Tamil Nadu 36679 36447 37127 105059 Uttar Pr. 1612310 654816 1039534 1157584 West Bengal 23057 30417 27985 36720 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 84700 154338 42568 2672334 520454 209323 36510 246363 1130511 225297 244710 207403 95204 901217 34918 2003-04 7 155239 262230 29351 2027755 1829962 118097 61011 377985 2306917 322908 124438 432338 127106 1360978 40017 214 Table 7: Revenue from Minor Irrigation (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 101324 81354 73995 16276 Bihar 12168 3575 4131 8041 Goa 1551 1980 1554 1960 Gujrat 21312 34531 38140 27988 Haryana 623 552 571 1079 Karnataka 7040 9023 12208 31769 Kerala 4746 5624 4630 8226 Madhya Pr. 89827 88687 77438 120218 Maharashtra 110753 170117 145931 55521 Orissa 8648 7682 19183 17033 Punjab 1578 2542 2846 1169 Rajasthan 114351 171182 232101 191564 Tamil Nadu 21897 25809 32269 29666 Uttar Pr. 219103 279404 405829 177312 West Bengal 46702 52875 50556 73739 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 13280 4551 113080 48004 686 35415 10369 105811 78294 19840 1334 267283 31678 121120 69181 2003-04 7 14437 16302 18065 108912 1229 42609 13833 72176 207033 37754 1358 182315 69675 185270 162817 Table 7a: Revenue from Total Surface Water (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 12069 4650 1335 170 Bihar 0 3575 0 4627 Goa 739 1761 971 1790 Gujrat 3842 7216 4993 14428 Haryana 623 552 571 1079 Karnataka 2575 2591 4605 20361 Kerala 4384 4973 4529 4547 Madhya Pr. 89827 88687 77438 119804 Maharashtra 110753 170117 145931 55521 Orissa 8648 7682 19183 17033 Punjab 9 906 693 263 Rajasthan 9500 9546 10307 11948 Tamil Nadu 127 2 672 3572 Uttar Pr. 210706 259862 207733 107788 West Bengal 42295 44512 45539 57183 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 105 3948 113001 27765 686 35438 7365 105811 78294 19840 11 11114 0 36639 53687 2003-04 7 564 8185 18012 92778 1229 39875 9121 72176 207033 33525 251 10831 0 185270 114061 215 Table 7b: Revenue from Total Ground Water (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 2253 2580 3878 431 999 Bihar 12168 0 4131 3412 421 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 2086 2592 712 1336 -768 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 4579 6539 7708 15304 0 Kerala 49 79 98 2980 1954 Madhya Pr. 0 0 0 1 0 Maharashtra 0 0 0 0 0 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 204 1392 448 474 630 Rajasthan 104851 161636 221794 179616 256169 Tamil Nadu 21527 25791 31579 25651 31678 Uttar Pr. 4507 19541 198096 32568 9984 West Bengal 1491 5136 1536 13484 14708 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 7c: Revenue from Total Water Tanks (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 2762 2544 266 24 120 Bihar 0 0 0 1920 2246 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 604 3013 2056 5303 18144 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 0 0 0 20361 21400 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 Maharashtra 223 2207 362 5319 7325 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 0 1 0 263 6 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 -2468 1775 5448 West Bengal 8509 9310 8613 11442 13406 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 5491 7631 0 3847 0 2758 4688 0 0 245 782 171484 69675 0 43239 2003-04 7 44 1488 0 74642 0 0 0 0 47473 0 224 0 0 122216 26440 216 Table 7d: Revenue from Total Lift Irrigation (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 1904 2024 1055 119 Bihar 0 0 0 155 Goa 393 1089 335 538 Gujrat 149 3506 2353 3755 Haryana 623 552 571 1079 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 Kerala 1955 1761 1490 1438 Madhya Pr. 0 0 0 0 Maharashtra 441 398 404 447 Orissa 0 0 0 0 Punjab 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 127 2 0 510 Uttar Pr. 166372 195775 201392 3094 West Bengal 33633 33054 36792 40985 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 236 264 107145 5228 686 0 1889 0 1301 0 0 0 0 7114 33390 2003-04 7 517 7 12146 11462 1229 0 1629 0 7168 3777 7 0 0 63053 65565 Table 8: Revenue from Industries (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 743 733 3460 91185 Bihar 3456 1915 2846 1608 Goa 64 6 41 10 Gujrat 12646 8945 21144 28686 Haryana 2881 4195 1545 1624 Karnataka 90617 174559 85468 -36618 Kerala 3600 2937 2760 1361 Madhya Pr. 24052 26497 38568 23068 Maharashtra 9227 9780 26639 1955 Orissa 1169 966 1739 832 Punjab 118 236 420 7061 Rajasthan 10924 26123 27158 7815 Tamil Nadu 2084 2147 2214 1764 Uttar Pr. 8265 16385 16440 413 West Bengal 75780 51955 53793 31297 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 5603 451 45 62475 306 36810 855 20895 976 952 1377 6464 1266 181 22801 2003-04 7 111438 266 329 65386 2668 97749 1207 24642 70267 229 151 8754 1759 356 39029 217 Table 9: Revenue from Non Ferrous and Metallurgical Industries (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 2756389 2849544 3575742 5991178 7796594 7715675 Bihar 6785420 7043479 7690875 392001 612033 733443 Goa 92878 91685 101064 131352 157811 193916 Gujrat 3810441 4104869 4266914 7345758 10728282 13423429 Haryana 184099 226509 231284 1398735 1188760 769835 Karnataka 411863 614473 1048311 1471318 1575533 2221480 Kerala 47031 54143 60582 162920 187606 183651 Madhya Pr. 4751152 5885088 8009416 21077 5906865 6467113 Maharashtra 1416111 2270250 2846513 3471661 4006057 4755013 Orissa 1310985 1700534 2417366 3785566 4435774 5520562 Punjab 10207 17842 18383 36997 74603 108654 Rajasthan 1630430 1827506 2145222 4129780 4493767 5136959 Tamil Nadu 535725 630278 672058 1603966 1810860 3775385 Uttar Pr. 611561 1203111 1481080 1901865 2625383 2510475 West Bengal 102896 121314 80583 79519 68688 139099 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Table 10: Revenue from Roads and Bridges (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 1 2 3 4 5 6 Andhra Pr. 103708 161247 134881 383259 462626 Bihar 79105 76746 91195 40521 104206 Goa 16036 19056 27209 33132 27822 Gujrat 20023 25691 26127 61317 44772 Haryana 439 531 1133 8302 7995 Karnataka 36920 54037 60103 192930 179222 Kerala 75081 80510 114343 141463 203037 Madhya Pr. 123204 189971 208052 35980 31374 Maharashtra 41662 70964 140777 5337 3758 Orissa 40118 46328 62979 130224 112482 Punjab 4715 13472 2340 910 10816 Rajasthan 19466 23660 38256 27849 39794 Tamil Nadu 155015 161557 121492 255538 266320 Uttar Pr. 173164 181818 160192 162653 179744 West Bengal 93874 80161 81512 204193 222988 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2003-04 7 274206 106263 40768 293623 6687 338036 186785 32596 6402 129031 1401 59494 245983 417926 220775 218 Table 1: Revenue Expenditure on Public Works (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 402062 468774 492689 422127 Bihar 458618 539596 542415 635696 Goa 72678 88403 90974 182602 Gujarat 354947 426921 691506 769393 Haryana 226060 340856 309287 375593 Karnataka 1055443 1138888 1322929 1926144 Kerala 135829 160348 273365 446629 Madhya Pr. 575149 387084 643665 489681 Maharashtra 1257440 563283 1136860 3616085 Orissa 181515 330607 421393 2417909 Punjab 448238 1001682 632842 1341161 Rajasthan 366399 267966 332412 543332 Tamil Nadu 760324 813782 967395 746678 Uttar Pr. 1522521 1440366 1813399 4809175 West Bengal 704754 829550 912901 1889625 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 252138 876513 183565 947587 796538 1981131 619733 556483 2593645 -243566 1449339 477807 956170 3702692 1614055 2003-04 7 386840 928180 193848 859528 691513 2101875 521418 694882 2941928 714209 1593206 496872 820496 4750345 1719727 Table 2: Capital Expenditure on Public Works (Machinery & Equipment and Maintenance & Repairs) (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 179379 192033 209136 71777 Bihar 19635 195880 129848 202094 Goa 36598 36301 41437 80557 Gujarat 243161 279771 201896 462756 Haryana 76665 80720 82288 89256 Karnataka 103265 113006 131847 401965 Kerala 90052 94571 127086 190716 Madhya Pr. 286676 304269 362736 268094 Maharashtra 1149615 1144351 1195308 1148948 Orissa 184497 206042 246549 509209 Punjab 238676 240601 261542 349055 Rajasthan 212317 247400 236166 299111 Tamil Nadu 338631 404125 499380 313101 Uttar Pr. 151493 148022 174744 167421 West Bengal 473100 540071 511485 775380 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 94072 422176 83321 611087 96007 473966 432501 320985 1165394 337619 342011 244395 601098 233627 2003-04 7 9393 505461 89423 540297 104261 557148 213358 362337 1478762 436329 69610 263375 821415 296155 604553 652525 219 Table 3: Capital Exp. on Public Works (excluding Machinery & Equipment and Maintenance & Repairs) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 222683 276742 283553 350350 Bihar 438983 343716 412567 433602 Goa 36080 52102 49537 102045 Gujarat 111786 147151 489610 306637 Haryana 149395 260136 226999 286337 Karnataka 952179 1025882 1191082 1524180 Kerala 45777 65778 146279 255913 Madhya Pr. 288473 82816 280929 221588 Maharashtra 107825 -581069 -58448 2467137 Orissa -2982 124565 174843 1908700 Punjab 209562 761081 371301 992106 Rajasthan 154082 20566 96246 244222 Tamil Nadu 421693 409657 468015 433577 Uttar Pr. 1371028 1292344 1638656 4641754 West Bengal 231654 289479 401415 1114245 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 158065 454337 100244 336500 700531 1507165 187232 235498 1428251 -581185 1107328 233413 355072 3469065 2003-04 7 377447 422719 104425 319231 587252 1544727 308060 332545 1463166 277880 1523596 233497 -919 4454190 1009502 1067202 Table 4: Revenue Expenditure on General Education, Sports, Art & Culture (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 14593866 16895224 17152478 37942024 Bihar 15637237 17023721 20090671 24781305 Goa 912028 990705 1194060 2376114 Gujarat 13692049 15609754 18711691 32581543 Haryana 4602491 5360323 6512960 14761448 Karnataka 12781222 14481330 17029522 35014063 Kerala 11454999 13510750 14351342 24709968 Madhya Pr. 12426705 13638200 16503104 21100399 Maharashtra 26470657 29948553 35980482 93819809 Orissa 6881552 8152360 9424832 17333443 Punjab 6876841 7656630 8954758 18322904 Rajasthan 12286696 14522764 16977895 34309775 Tamil Nadu 17409210 19203415 21805917 42928688 Uttar Pr. 23580826 28664045 33831738 60423781 West Bengal 16334189 17793833 19569438 45434129 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 40257366 27035118 2775990 36239832 14471810 35640113 29675613 22955795 89371019 18827919 20918434 33105439 41453271 60670518 2003-04 7 46657704 28217622 2806175 36834003 15358726 37660212 30801187 23553393 94323003 18818334 20803782 36348853 41750611 62545827 44008066 45191912 220 Table 5: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 13829133 16116128 16338290 35933271 Bihar 15357578 16740037 19778938 24489163 Goa 822257 889427 1053082 2059251 Gujarat 13100439 14955497 17956316 31359383 Haryana 4363770 5064142 6191995 14010404 Karnataka 12108624 13689949 16118351 33563170 Kerala 10767711 12738521 13478721 23080581 Madhya Pr. 11765407 12833656 15498071 20062352 Maharashtra 24596140 27967346 33858863 90451220 Orissa 6598971 7744328 9006075 16942629 Punjab 6476554 7060732 8329093 17622896 Rajasthan 11914345 14112317 16531033 33591331 Tamil Nadu 16510928 18080189 20594635 41117249 Uttar Pr. 22506469 27516542 32550864 59067661 West Bengal 15761946 17138034 18885735 43859842 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 37909119 26728430 2423794 34816856 13799523 33996388 27875829 21614098 85380642 18370146 20131001 32424351 39539279 59168323 2003-04 7 42895581 27776291 2415908 35255414 14606361 36099357 28866226 22303232 90142004 18339405 20019267 35649424 40048250 61063474 42677084 43871367 Table 6: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 9320898 11265449 11451664 24016045 Bihar 2162972 1908693 2171970 3154757 Goa 409813 454940 531293 1081592 Gujarat 5401813 6044615 7719168 12648571 Haryana 576285 648266 786067 1795696 Karnataka 9895841 11446388 13407206 28487125 Kerala 6575915 7734673 8008821 14722629 Madhya Pr. 1252976 1459902 2231366 2801791 Maharashtra 23160104 26893281 32654714 89104750 Orissa 1854957 2474063 3005737 2818319 Punjab 1078846 1221659 1403998 2235636 Rajasthan 3759529 4651542 5451794 11453741 Tamil Nadu 5872313 6540887 7361904 15253814 Uttar Pr. 19523692 23924286 27210419 53564457 West Bengal 9173063 10151101 17458537 39476135 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 25585083 3910428 1359772 14984083 1572533 28537225 18231934 4033511 83590204 2133899 2679237 10309543 14893205 53401289 2003-04 7 29426484 4759456 1252279 15484797 1786369 29911004 18806218 4673733 88284388 2204921 2168541 11790611 14559925 55960890 38883807 40282314 221 Table 7: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 4508235 4850679 4886627 11917226 Bihar 13194606 14831345 17606968 21334406 Goa 412444 434488 521788 977659 Gujarat 7698625 8910882 10237148 18710812 Haryana 3787485 4415876 5405929 12214709 Karnataka 2212783 2243561 2711145 5076046 Kerala 4191796 5003848 5469899 8357951 Madhya Pr. 10512431 11373754 13266705 17260561 Maharashtra 1436036 1074064 1204149 1346470 Orissa 4744014 5270265 6000338 14124310 Punjab 5397708 5839073 6925095 15387260 Rajasthan 8154816 9460775 11079238 22137590 Tamil Nadu 10638615 11539302 13232730 25863434 Uttar Pr. 2982777 3592256 5340445 5503205 West Bengal 6588883 6986932 1427198 4383708 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 12324037 22818001 1064022 19832774 12226990 5459163 9643895 17580586 1790439 16236247 17451764 22114808 24646074 5767033 2003-04 7 13469097 23016835 1163629 19770617 12819992 6188353 10060008 17629499 1857616 16134484 17850726 23858813 25488325 5102584 3793277 3589053 Table 8: Revenue Expenditure on Technical Education (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 445468 463353 482814 876813 1229056 1036296 Bihar 184693 188593 196946 148111 157401 253032 Goa 40438 47284 72993 141943 152365 161347 Gujarat 390741 437619 504103 896678 1058520 1119347 Haryana 123595 152801 162354 385736 386757 427616 Karnataka 310051 382222 409341 734855 873985 695463 Kerala 486639 550361 592180 1176601 1204747 1303543 Madhya Pr. 439535 533427 670567 676809 889828 787806 Maharashtra 1106669 1478255 1530647 2394350 2787068 2721577 Orissa 147506 246865 257180 191179 236165 227158 Punjab 186208 348646 380399 228278 323978 366917 Rajasthan 191595 229681 241728 406475 366085 346323 Tamil Nadu 585452 616894 638041 1256690 1141446 1059765 Uttar Pr. 678974 751684 823516 754439 693870 664990 West Bengal 318557 364455 373872 757289 675126 615546 Source: Comptroller and Auditor General of India, Finance Accounts, Different States, Relevant Years. 222 Table 9: Revenue Expenditure on Technical Education (Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 133970 150297 153003 247001 271668 226566 Bihar 25217 24714 27392 30087 27938 19829 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujarat 11456 14542 18806 36718 43010 45767 Haryana 25831 33649 32176 112291 141213 172323 Karnataka 121652 119294 118167 327968 447926 252407 Kerala 162242 170673 176106 352585 376061 417354 Madhya Pr. 139808 147139 189358 209381 428970 337451 Maharashtra 597296 669838 880115 1411548 1798022 1608036 Orissa 12530 22331 9020 10685 2020 1349 Punjab 15414 31161 21132 20630 47993 0 Rajasthan 83636 102131 119949 165557 166596 137169 Tamil Nadu 122132 124421 125967 307353 251408 219227 Uttar Pr. 277649 300631 284549 192384 140871 123439 West Bengal 69028 73352 69878 135292 115160 128569 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 10: Revenue Expenditure on Technical Education (excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 311498 313056 329811 629812 Bihar 159476 163879 169554 118024 Goa 40438 47284 72993 141943 Gujarat 379285 423077 485296 859960 Haryana 97764 119152 130178 273445 Karnataka 188399 262929 291174 406887 Kerala 324397 379688 416074 824016 Madhya Pr. 299728 386288 481209 467429 Maharashtra 509373 808417 650531 982802 Orissa 134976 224534 248160 180494 Punjab 170794 317485 359267 207648 Rajasthan 107960 127550 121778 240918 Tamil Nadu 463320 492473 512074 949337 Uttar Pr. 401325 451053 538967 562055 West Bengal 249528 291102 303994 621997 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 957389 129464 152365 1015510 245544 426059 828686 460858 989046 234145 275985 199489 890038 552999 2003-04 7 809730 233203 161347 1073580 255293 443056 886189 450355 1113541 225809 366917 209154 840538 541550 559966 486977 223 Table 11: Revenue Expenditure on Sports & Youth Services (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 167176 152122 167686 808124 Bihar 70387 68809 83862 97636 Goa 25565 28727 31279 102387 Gujarat 128566 137763 155410 192228 Haryana 104158 130934 143076 300247 Karnataka 171930 213603 266215 304934 Kerala 112983 115325 149546 214517 Madhya Pr. 137884 189100 221969 170026 Maharashtra 598750 278878 342875 532457 Orissa 94953 114973 114794 107077 Punjab 184205 212880 203436 310172 Rajasthan 111273 108083 117429 161787 Tamil Nadu 138264 244221 354504 224165 Uttar Pr. 296533 307648 322136 374222 West Bengal 178767 208919 224625 687675 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 792824 102231 115162 217332 242139 298157 293375 249407 688682 113304 227701 178158 329234 446027 2003-04 7 2357913 99804 132769 232542 256740 354839 299224 248086 713369 125113 203427 211151 290838 447553 476156 541014 Table 12: Revenue Expenditure on Sports & Youth Services (Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 0 399 27 85304 128960 141502 Bihar 0 0 0 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujarat 786 943 55 2213 2585 4956 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 35012 40988 44390 42304 37944 38288 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 10494 13486 19272 0 0 2847 Maharashtra 1231 3269 1730 11085 5313 10212 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 1795 2050 1690 1250 1150 1050 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 275 271 264 12127 4629 812 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 224 Table 13: Revenue Expenditure on Sports & Youth Services (excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 167176 151723 167659 722820 Bihar 70387 68809 83862 97636 Goa 25565 28727 31279 102387 Gujarat 127780 136820 155355 190015 Haryana 104158 130934 143076 300247 Karnataka 136918 172615 221825 262630 Kerala 112983 115325 149546 214517 Madhya Pr. 127390 175614 202697 170026 Maharashtra 597519 275608 341145 521372 Orissa 94953 114973 114794 107077 Punjab 184205 212880 203436 310172 Rajasthan 109478 106033 115739 160537 Tamil Nadu 138264 244221 354504 224165 Uttar Pr. 296533 307648 322136 374222 West Bengal 178493 208648 224361 675548 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 663865 102231 115162 214747 242139 260213 293375 249407 683369 113304 227701 177008 329234 446027 2003-04 7 2216411 99804 132769 227586 256740 316551 299224 245239 703157 125113 203427 210101 290838 447553 471528 540202 Table 14: Revenue Expenditure on Art & Culture (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 152088 163621 163688 323816 Bihar 24579 26281 30924 46395 Goa 23768 25267 36707 72533 Gujarat 72303 78875 95862 133254 Haryana 10968 12447 15535 65060 Karnataka 190618 195556 235615 411103 Kerala 87666 106543 130896 238269 Madhya Pr. 83878 82017 112498 191212 Maharashtra 169098 224075 248097 441783 Orissa 40121 46194 46783 92558 Punjab 29873 34372 41830 161557 Rajasthan 69482 72683 87706 150182 Tamil Nadu 174565 262111 218738 330584 Uttar Pr. 98850 88171 135222 227459 West Bengal 74919 82425 85206 129322 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 326366 47057 84669 147125 43391 471582 301662 202463 514627 108303 235754 136844 443312 362298 2003-04 7 367914 88495 96150 226700 68009 510553 332194 214269 746053 126658 214171 141955 351758 369811 179699 163986 225 Table 15: Revenue Expenditure on Art & Culture (Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 0 420 0 0 1050 1050 Bihar 191 250 271 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujarat 5655 6249 5266 11326 10881 11775 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 0 0 1162 0 0 931 Kerala 0 0 1 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 5841 3174 6548 5800 9835 6934 Maharashtra 27461 35804 -1106 3529 0 12040 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 0 0 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 16: Revenue Expenditure on Art & Culture (excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 152088 163201 163688 323816 Bihar 24387 26031 30653 46395 Goa 23768 25267 36707 72533 Gujarat 66648 72626 90596 121927 Haryana 10968 12447 15535 65060 Karnataka 190618 195556 234454 411103 Kerala 87666 106543 130895 238269 Madhya Pr. 78038 78843 105951 185412 Maharashtra 141637 188271 249203 438255 Orissa 40121 46194 46783 92558 Punjab 29873 34372 41830 161557 Rajasthan 69482 72683 87706 150182 Tamil Nadu 174565 262111 218738 330584 Uttar Pr. 98850 88171 135222 227459 West Bengal 74919 82425 85206 129322 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 325316 47057 84669 136244 43391 471582 301662 192628 514627 108303 235754 136844 443312 362298 2003-04 7 366864 88495 96150 214925 68009 509622 332194 207335 734013 126658 214171 141955 351758 369811 179699 163986 226 Table 17: Capital Expenditure on General Education (Secondary Education: TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 14274602 16579481 16821104 36810084 Bihar 15542271 16928630 19975884 24637274 Goa 862695 936712 1126074 2201194 Gujarat 13491180 15393116 18460419 32256061 Haryana 4487365 5216943 6354349 14396141 Karnataka 12418675 14072172 16527692 34298025 Kerala 11254350 13288882 14070900 24257182 Madhya Pr. 12204943 13367083 16168638 20739161 Maharashtra 25702809 29445600 35389510 92845569 Orissa 6746477 7991192 9263255 17133808 Punjab 6662762 7409378 8709492 17851174 Rajasthan 12105941 14341997 16772760 33997805 Tamil Nadu 17096380 18697083 21232675 42373938 Uttar Pr. 23185443 28268226 33374380 59822100 West Bengal 16080503 17502488 19259607 44617132 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 39138176 26885831 2576159 35875376 14186280 34870374 29080576 22503926 88167710 18606312 20454979 32790437 40680725 59862193 2003-04 7 43931877 28029323 2577256 36374761 15033977 36794820 30169769 23091038 92863581 18566563 20386184 35995747 41108015 61728463 43352210 44486912 Table 18: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Elementary Education: TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 6050368 7223097 7246894 16594274 Bihar 9923184 11192364 13502031 15850801 Goa 247095 270924 317689 589290 Gujarat 7316769 8452588 9873067 17651539 Haryana 2053233 2388894 2998619 6664859 Karnataka 6511001 7165647 8581860 17847388 Kerala 5247841 6539234 6723372 10460522 Madhya Pr. 7442009 8092194 9848563 13504375 Maharashtra 11619958 12751815 16061336 50072055 Orissa 3882118 4450596 5094293 9826086 Punjab 2174516 2260310 2657588 4589245 Rajasthan 6461951 7912907 9396401 18874781 Tamil Nadu 8087916 8868284 9972429 18752839 Uttar Pr. 11165784 15122580 19132186 37515134 West Bengal 5598502 5869922 6578739 15417538 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 17286863 17314910 591708 19581278 6868824 17957800 12356315 14512406 40755799 10774161 5796795 18751186 17806156 34588596 2003-04 7 20103213 17501003 530281 19240216 7122594 20242846 12847327 15754025 41144047 10831111 5074466 20335942 17521479 36035379 14221743 14926704 227 Table 19: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Elementary Education: Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 States 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 4902813 6006940 6030806 12819634 13585226 15996709 Bihar 184099 150000 165663 65723 308292 253382 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujarat 175227 211771 375322 389495 788821 624476 Haryana 30434 33085 35695 91807 87015 72926 Karnataka 5478627 6295162 7274069 16084410 15926240 17639288 Kerala 3124068 3826581 3828673 6560174 8019413 8278285 Madhya Pr. 355013 430166 846905 1683901 2371334 3404753 Maharashtra 11141490 12332414 15561654 49151289 39311236 39546327 Orissa 123509 237279 229974 272451 138124 210021 Punjab 16636 20016 23014 61034 34364 70000 Rajasthan 2690265 3441999 4065035 8625876 8177827 9372798 Tamil Nadu 2608984 2886607 3213590 5979756 5531623 5395706 Uttar Pr. 10159447 13909674 16930125 35693559 32855639 34833417 West Bengal 0 0 6271921 13450619 12873558 13466387 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 20: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Elementary Education: excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 1147555 1216157 1216088 3774639 Bihar 9739086 11042364 13336368 15785078 Goa 247095 270924 317689 589290 Gujarat 7141542 8240817 9497745 17262044 Haryana 2022799 2355809 2962924 6573052 Karnataka 1032373 870485 1307791 1762978 Kerala 2123773 2712653 2894699 3900349 Madhya Pr. 7086996 7662028 9001658 11820474 Maharashtra 478468 419401 499682 920766 Orissa 3758609 4213317 4864319 9553635 Punjab 2157880 2240294 2634574 4528211 Rajasthan 3771685 4470908 5331366 10248905 Tamil Nadu 5478932 5981677 6758839 12773083 Uttar Pr. 1006337 1212906 2202061 1821576 West Bengal 5598502 5869922 306818 1966919 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 3701637 17006618 591708 18792457 6781809 2031560 4336902 12141071 1444563 10636037 5762431 10573359 12274532 1732956 2003-04 7 4106504 17247621 530281 18615740 7049668 2603558 4569042 12349272 1597720 10621090 5004466 10963144 12125773 1201962 1348185 1460317 228 Table 21: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Secondary Education: TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 4413144 5146237 5370811 11105837 Bihar 3275056 3405742 3879598 5145516 Goa 437500 480021 557899 1184899 Gujarat 4373171 4934608 6179798 10422207 Haryana 1607801 1866587 2229036 5238859 Karnataka 3652132 4217694 5067352 10582603 Kerala 3339515 4009045 4334067 7552272 Madhya Pr. 2773580 3041326 3573816 3768775 Maharashtra 9660729 11431253 13578976 31468894 Orissa 1657760 1920039 2282198 3708955 Punjab 3318620 3667400 4372825 11189190 Rajasthan 4189737 4764170 5466836 10947377 Tamil Nadu 6140937 6810886 7858700 16271270 Uttar Pr. 8311201 9213105 10293185 16049196 West Bengal 7740057 8506375 9390800 21431305 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 12190865 5144904 1493510 11528087 5025413 10542663 9563024 3767017 34285719 4783763 11596557 10882846 16157882 19374205 2003-04 7 13500098 5300186 1499026 12049851 5287347 10288741 10640226 3688938 39755528 4709394 12359809 12010962 16225403 19347684 21558986 22159303 Table 22: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Secondary Education: Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 3495095 4177066 4374320 8715519 Bihar 166073 162799 110000 118602 Goa 364256 402089 465865 928330 Gujarat 4058536 4547641 5710104 9320774 Haryana 108603 119930 121507 589186 Karnataka 2953051 3409074 4130541 8657896 Kerala 1697875 2177593 2354768 4130521 Madhya Pr. 423068 529262 679236 283620 Maharashtra 9486016 11632272 13957585 32167960 Orissa 1221691 1436936 1764373 757880 Punjab 365412 384622 437390 1029328 Rajasthan 370133 425928 477992 1098522 Tamil Nadu 2116807 2371259 2742435 5951139 Uttar Pr. 6699762 7352531 8001474 13505413 West Bengal 7368522 7938008 8939330 20462559 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 9497666 148931 1177890 10921720 336000 8582214 5451890 438211 34989051 350409 962752 972091 5886371 16509025 2003-04 7 10400259 241132 1069355 11447914 320228 8271705 6296496 469415 40492077 361994 964454 1090532 5914891 16611196 20509475 21366059 229 Table 23: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Secondary Education: excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 918049 969171 996491 2390318 Bihar 3108982 3242942 3769598 5026914 Goa 73244 77931 92034 256569 Gujarat 314636 386966 469694 1101433 Haryana 1499198 1746657 2107529 4649673 Karnataka 699081 808620 936811 1924707 Kerala 1641640 1831452 1979298 3421751 Madhya Pr. 2350512 2512065 2894580 3485156 Maharashtra 174713 -201019 -378609 -699067 Orissa 436068 483102 517825 2951075 Punjab 2953207 3282778 3935434 10159862 Rajasthan 3819603 4338242 4988844 9848855 Tamil Nadu 4024130 4439627 5116265 10320130 Uttar Pr. 1611439 1860574 2291711 2543782 West Bengal 371535 568367 451470 968747 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 2693199 4995974 315621 606367 4689413 1960449 4111134 3328805 -703331 4433353 10633805 9910755 10271511 2865180 2003-04 7 3099839 5059054 429671 601937 4967119 2017036 4343730 3219523 -736549 4347400 11395355 10920430 10310512 2736488 1049511 793244 Table 24: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Uni. & Higher Education: TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 3104706 3482103 3504443 7650210 Bihar 1843297 1642088 1927801 3093453 Goa 116382 121553 158153 249692 Gujarat 1236840 1366392 1730917 3084830 Haryana 653765 741392 899825 2014135 Karnataka 1765274 2012078 2185477 4450604 Kerala 2080492 2093288 2220871 4885656 Madhya Pr. 1390844 1522050 1873851 2672025 Maharashtra 2649916 3050477 3259120 8028655 Orissa 937689 1258126 1511372 3205460 Punjab 917792 1049514 1210691 1715066 Rajasthan 982312 1108385 1275318 3217918 Tamil Nadu 1729763 1887631 2103859 4901614 Uttar Pr. 2740941 2878884 2502190 4742822 West Bengal 2033611 2376857 2558536 6105834 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 7843518 3585504 290920 3401632 1821176 4764683 5509144 3146234 9297108 2639922 2591663 2279101 4884849 4461732 2003-04 7 8701973 4421202 344991 3491590 2097169 4760152 5012172 2766285 8476329 2640481 2437779 2712073 4608735 4971071 6002480 5957304 230 Table 25: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Uni. & Higher Education: Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 922787 1075269 1046478 2456573 Bihar 1805549 1580761 1868838 2970432 Goa 101257 101050 134938 204299 Gujarat 1162589 1279673 1628278 2889056 Haryana 437249 495251 628865 1114703 Karnataka 1431722 1650624 1803907 3608069 Kerala 1753973 1730500 1825177 4031935 Madhya Pr. 423068 529262 679236 283620 Maharashtra 2505333 2896040 3075932 7731247 Orissa 502413 795346 1000095 1764133 Punjab 696799 817021 943593 1145273 Rajasthan 695493 779226 902321 1719829 Tamil Nadu 1145417 1282226 1404795 3322919 Uttar Pr. 2628207 2658605 2278125 4365485 West Bengal 1802683 2165414 2224799 5561990 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 2491249 3453206 243082 3196191 1149518 3884767 4760631 438211 8995398 1625152 1682121 1147202 3475211 4036625 2003-04 7 3019431 4264942 274710 3263876 1393215 3854485 4231437 469415 8178725 1623706 1134087 1313279 3249328 4516277 5499774 5449217 Table 26: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Uni. & Higher Education: excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 2181920 2406835 2457965 5193636 Bihar 37749 61327 58963 123021 Goa 15126 20502 23215 45393 Gujarat 74251 86718 102639 195774 Haryana 216516 246141 270960 899433 Karnataka 333551 361454 381570 842535 Kerala 326519 362788 395694 853721 Madhya Pr. 967776 992789 1194615 2388406 Maharashtra 144583 154437 183189 297408 Orissa 435276 462780 511277 1441327 Punjab 220993 232493 267097 569793 Rajasthan 286820 329160 372997 1498088 Tamil Nadu 584346 605405 699064 1578695 Uttar Pr. 112734 220279 224065 377337 West Bengal 230928 211443 333737 543844 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 5352269 132298 47838 205441 671658 879916 748513 2708023 301710 1014770 909542 1131899 1409637 425106 2003-04 7 5682542 156260 70280 227714 703954 905667 780735 2296870 297604 1016775 1303692 1398794 1359407 454794 502706 508087 231 Table 27: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Adult Education: TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 114629 99555 36860 231952 Bihar 38295 93688 125575 37827 Goa 10225 5345 5739 7158 Gujarat 56133 64172 61987 9033 Haryana 11363 16358 12666 9636 Karnataka 86447 97545 72611 44617 Kerala 16044 10306 6079 3819 Madhya Pr. 105978 113511 135241 43363 Maharashtra 92132 143893 123424 89573 Orissa 47955 35734 40828 13355 Punjab 4140 14036 5373 2302 Rajasthan 46023 74644 125115 31890 Tamil Nadu 101623 200047 99988 11643 Uttar Pr. 61841 72385 27098 0 West Bengal 54812 96422 70453 116579 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 119679 89300 7702 11409 7441 54231 1646 39940 100794 18574 11063 29650 9890 0 2003-04 7 119256 37845 6341 11968 7620 53451 2570 15104 98178 17258 7847 32349 5113 0 37154 32298 Table 28: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Adult Education: Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 States 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 203 6147 46 24750 10553 9967 Bihar 7252 15132 27469 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujarat 5150 5000 5000 0 0 0 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 8767 27022 34297 33996 37686 38856 Kerala 0 0 203 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 18851 24584 29878 2273 0 0 Maharashtra 2713 3254 9330 0 0 0 Orissa 2052 2004 6580 2568 5503 3883 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 857 987 1228 1885 2320 2424 Tamil Nadu 1105 795 1084 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 36276 3477 695 0 0 0 West Bengal 1858 47679 22487 967 1000 652 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 232 Table 29: Revenue Expenditure on General Education (Adult Education: excluding Assistance) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 114425 93408 36814 207202 Bihar 31043 78556 98106 37827 Goa 10225 5345 5739 7158 Gujarat 50983 59172 56987 9033 Haryana 11363 16358 12666 9636 Karnataka 77681 70523 38314 10621 Kerala 16044 10306 5876 3819 Madhya Pr. 87127 88926 105364 41091 Maharashtra 89419 140639 114093 89573 Orissa 45902 33731 34248 10788 Punjab 4140 14036 5373 2302 Rajasthan 45166 73657 123886 30004 Tamil Nadu 100517 199252 98903 11643 Uttar Pr. 25564 68908 26403 0 West Bengal 52955 48743 47966 115611 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 109126 89300 7702 11409 7441 16545 1646 39940 100794 13071 11063 27330 9890 0 2003-04 7 109289 37845 6341 11968 7620 14595 2570 15104 98178 13375 7847 29925 5113 0 36154 31646 Table 30: Revenue Expenditure on Total Medical and Public Health (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 4074686 4379018 4758640 10416268 Bihar 2914654 3106250 3440006 3692750 Goa 334973 349519 403987 829610 Gujrat 2954276 3439655 3917537 6268663 Haryana 982900 1131415 1292400 2652095 Karnataka 3281993 3765595 4049805 7862053 Kerala 2392789 2859158 3375641 6267781 Madhya Pr. 3310308 3712273 3850140 5800443 Maharashtra 5994125 6728672 7582883 15817733 Orissa 1450180 1655699 1936072 3586552 Punjab 1892716 2014375 2188799 5778798 Rajasthan 3079335 3586562 4078206 7676822 Tamil Nadu 4475096 4993877 5758216 9666265 Uttar Pr. 6834578 6501848 7871049 10920197 West Bengal 4349384 4545678 5265363 11521829 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 10911694 4032154 887185 8468669 2879235 7937081 6663097 6587935 15043290 3869468 5743527 7488458 9499697 12911966 2003-04 7 12003840 3880151 996501 7611073 3059640 7890262 7197515 6759279 16245872 3884036 5562967 8096241 9984620 13922469 11703241 11909378 233 Table31: Revenue Expenditure on Total Urban Health Services (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 2095458 2112420 2377312 5275706 Bihar 1040011 1147005 1196301 1122813 Goa 188664 198552 220886 461271 Gujrat 1374828 1585930 1790527 3119421 Haryana 331786 387948 463164 923360 Karnataka 1297146 1416510 1505227 3271007 Kerala 1367424 1652925 1989666 3369747 Madhya Pr. 1434464 1603824 1808568 2405212 Maharashtra 2574562 2817267 3130839 5729500 Orissa 544200 633121 762649 1513510 Punjab 758724 807415 836172 2709362 Rajasthan 1332619 1556084 1738002 3263492 Tamil Nadu 2292897 2611314 3231788 5384865 Uttar Pr. 2360282 2447132 2924135 4257799 West Bengal 2631450 2706484 3070356 7023618 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 4896644 1495090 473088 3357628 995536 3274899 3703517 2722779 5699463 1321234 2469050 3151686 5582767 4712620 2003-04 7 4764954 1427696 535425 3563910 1083309 3122615 3954963 2898864 6983249 1552567 2474058 3446249 5689993 5501511 7031419 7182057 Table 32: Revenue Expenditure on Urban Health Services Allopathy (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 1970146 1983913 2232637 5006654 Bihar 1010933 1117367 1140886 1072623 Goa 188168 198082 220381 460148 Gujrat 1289410 1490875 1691115 2952226 Haryana 324155 378998 452801 902402 Karnataka 1273589 1395639 1479515 3224614 Kerala 1141984 1378572 1685620 2822266 Madhya Pr. 1361265 1516023 1721182 2240411 Maharashtra 2433232 2672388 2937820 5494296 Orissa 521999 607785 733767 1455951 Punjab 720915 762616 788410 2615422 Rajasthan 1173679 1367717 1523362 2867254 Tamil Nadu 2221419 2530724 3138893 5165543 Uttar Pr. 2188999 2169276 2744898 3953192 West Bengal 2592409 2658585 3019094 6881740 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 4612199 1487267 471821 3154069 993185 3225796 3057322 2548804 5481288 1261713 2362935 2713432 5359098 4374897 2003-04 7 4460378 1379254 534602 3356535 1056984 3070612 3196896 2717391 6471209 1494686 2366926 3023584 5447920 5132748 6862267 7012337 234 Table 33: Revenue Expenditure on Urban Health Services Other Systems (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 125312 128507 144675 269052 Bihar 29078 29638 55416 50190 Goa 496 470 505 1123 Gujrat 85418 95056 99412 167195 Haryana 7630 8949 10363 20958 Karnataka 23558 20871 25712 46392 Kerala 225440 274353 304046 547481 Madhya Pr. 73199 87801 87386 164801 Maharashtra 141330 144879 193018 235205 Orissa 22201 25336 28882 57559 Punjab 37809 44799 47762 93940 Rajasthan 158940 188367 214640 396238 Tamil Nadu 71478 80590 92895 219322 Uttar Pr. 171284 277857 179237 304607 West Bengal 39041 47898 51262 141879 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 284445 7823 1267 203559 2351 49103 646195 173975 218175 59521 106116 438255 223669 337724 2003-04 7 304576 48442 824 207375 26325 52003 758067 181473 512040 57881 107132 422665 242073 368764 169152 169720 Table 34: Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Urban Health Services Other systems (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 States 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 0 0 0 36 0 0 Bihar 254 0 1617 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 1518 1865 1965 3340 3985 5049 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 0 0 Kerala 0 0 2112 16940 17167 20232 Madhya Pr. 852 4236 675 0 0 383 Maharashtra 0 0 0 0 0 0 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 23429 27634 32466 66514 66118 73316 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 381 367 544 1021 0 0 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 0 0 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 235 Table 35: Revenue Expenditure on Urban Health Services Other Systems - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 125312 128507 144675 269016 Bihar 28823 29638 53798 50190 Goa 496 470 505 1123 Gujrat 83900 93190 97447 163855 Haryana 7630 8949 10363 20958 Karnataka 23558 20871 25712 46392 Kerala 225440 274353 301934 530540 Madhya Pr. 72347 83564 86711 164801 Maharashtra 141330 144879 193018 235205 Orissa 22201 25336 28882 57559 Punjab 37809 44799 47762 93940 Rajasthan 135511 160732 182174 329724 Tamil Nadu 71478 80590 92895 219322 Uttar Pr. 170902 277490 178692 303586 West Bengal 39041 47898 51262 141879 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 284445 7823 1267 199574 2351 49103 629028 173975 218175 59521 106116 372136 223669 337724 2003-04 7 304576 48442 824 202326 26325 52003 737835 181090 512040 57881 107132 349349 242073 368764 169152 169720 Table 36: Revenue Expenditure on Total Rural Health Services (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 632102 714253 830603 2011496 Bihar 1235532 1282918 1461314 2048348 Goa 71617 71339 84727 154443 Gujrat 618444 704120 821370 1329976 Haryana 232797 274027 339498 726744 Karnataka 43919 49108 38245 159039 Kerala 476550 561885 617701 1232134 Madhya Pr. 933171 1093351 1108791 1935322 Maharashtra 211086 165809 216169 497371 Orissa 485523 519834 606184 1106868 Punjab 709594 767211 894213 2101290 Rajasthan 1032050 1236799 1396255 2985797 Tamil Nadu 798041 856186 990043 1789218 Uttar Pr. 2142103 1752313 2323982 3789525 West Bengal 737614 802291 960611 2100800 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 2580585 2085746 158043 1650470 768587 290283 1232855 2134412 425432 1417574 2251552 2956690 1518804 4522023 2003-04 7 3257957 1709408 160091 1821856 827738 257082 1340144 2241281 324185 1396829 2060164 3223538 1711224 4820155 2318357 2456684 236 Table 37: Revenue Expenditure on Rural Health Services Allopathy (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 586131 657674 762776 1860684 Bihar 1223242 1269007 1449696 2031310 Goa 71617 71339 84727 154443 Gujrat 593120 665817 779888 1254325 Haryana 172461 205892 255677 557429 Karnataka 37408 41122 29432 141590 Kerala 471293 551034 603614 1162197 Madhya Pr. 708876 853804 817312 1557840 Maharashtra 167017 120129 154918 311283 Orissa 421594 451187 526698 922606 Punjab 646949 704074 803007 1925947 Rajasthan 678582 830490 932252 2008792 Tamil Nadu 755434 808277 936066 1684971 Uttar Pr. 1398998 1357317 1700583 2759409 West Bengal 691545 745942 843669 1864496 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 2413862 2079250 158043 1546347 590088 272568 1217007 1751151 283759 1219731 2077069 2006205 1404573 3425069 2003-04 7 3089315 1667800 160091 1702771 628527 236908 1322239 1854122 309512 1192041 1878566 2162744 1571229 3665446 2073179 2206492 Table 38: Revenue Expenditure on Rural Health Services Other Systems (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 States 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 45971 56579 67828 150812 166724 168642 Bihar 12289 13911 11618 17038 6497 41608 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 25324 38304 41482 75651 104123 119085 Haryana 60336 68134 83821 169315 178499 199211 Karnataka 6511 7986 8813 17450 17715 20174 Kerala 5257 10851 14087 69937 15848 17905 Madhya Pr. 224295 239547 291478 377482 383261 387159 Maharashtra 44069 45680 61251 186088 141673 14673 Orissa 63929 68647 79485 184261 197843 204788 Punjab 62645 63136 91206 175343 174483 181598 Rajasthan 353469 406309 464003 977004 950485 1060794 Tamil Nadu 42606 47909 53976 104247 114232 139995 Uttar Pr. 743105 394996 623399 1030117 1096954 1154709 West Bengal 46068 56349 116942 236304 245178 250192 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 237 Table 39: Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Rural Health Services (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 3436 3439 3837 33519 35330 103823 Bihar 14542 47351 21170 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 73278 90390 102095 199218 240376 236021 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 180 132 164 345 350 422 Kerala 2717 3012 12642 40410 39944 39418 Madhya Pr. 127661 178162 139432 363453 527828 504388 Maharashtra 0 0 0 1437 1249 1529 Orissa 28795 28358 63709 103147 36464 30615 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 9522 11685 11012 18527 18950 18178 Uttar Pr. 260 0 275 0 211 1311 West Bengal 10432 11530 14385 51923 135514 116264 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 40: Revenue Expenditure on Rural Health Services - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 628666 710814 826766 1977977 Bihar 1220990 1235566 1440144 2048348 Goa 71617 71339 84727 154443 Gujrat 545166 613730 719274 1130758 Haryana 232797 274027 339498 726744 Karnataka 43739 48976 38081 158694 Kerala 473834 558873 605060 1191724 Madhya Pr. 805511 915189 969359 1571869 Maharashtra 211086 165809 216169 495933 Orissa 456728 491476 542475 1003721 Punjab 709594 767211 894213 2101290 Rajasthan 1032050 1236799 1396255 2985797 Tamil Nadu 788519 844501 979031 1770691 Uttar Pr. 2141843 1752313 2323707 3789525 West Bengal 727182 790761 946227 2048877 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 2545255 2085746 158043 1410094 768587 289933 1192911 1606584 424184 1381110 2251552 2956690 1499854 4521813 2003-04 7 3154134 1709408 160091 1585835 827738 256660 1300726 1736893 322656 1366214 2060164 3223538 1693046 4818844 2182844 2340420 238 Table 41: Revenue Expenditure on Medical Education, Training and Research (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 357282 402355 431743 932827 Bihar 264948 281929 303801 271891 Goa 36929 40577 45758 100696 Gujrat 314669 367408 427916 887018 Haryana 206874 232399 258613 545769 Karnataka 345107 430214 448318 1266241 Kerala 319402 372752 422392 1146597 Madhya Pr. 235936 301321 286356 475943 Maharashtra 552329 564231 627916 1436048 Orissa 117128 135001 157130 370659 Punjab 183013 189949 207255 571507 Rajasthan 311936 346832 378463 765313 Tamil Nadu 610865 671494 551086 951743 Uttar Pr. 772131 854945 872875 1631957 West Bengal 336628 373900 478553 1038996 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 1061964 345428 117641 984633 656720 1264388 1116847 558748 1443991 305814 592027 730301 1021970 2051908 2003-04 7 1098333 460683 133583 1018835 670902 1177316 1208144 569167 1580411 330411 606815 768919 1029640 1961341 1088944 1099557 Table 42: Revenue Expenditure on Public Health (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 968567 1123530 1095427 1856980 Bihar 374164 394397 478590 249697 Goa 29259 31022 38644 67381 Gujrat 642523 777602 870167 917414 Haryana 203480 228370 221249 427039 Karnataka 265283 319312 331069 453327 Kerala 229414 271596 345746 517607 Madhya Pr. 704258 711434 644426 978753 Maharashtra 2649947 3175199 3600154 8142916 Orissa 288108 350980 390965 561999 Punjab 231615 237234 239306 377686 Rajasthan 402730 446847 565486 662219 Tamil Nadu 761666 842226 971209 1516905 Uttar Pr. 1552097 1439462 1749656 1229322 West Bengal 636059 655553 747353 1342346 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 2096367 105889 68831 1188308 439369 468847 595691 1161965 7461469 787328 411813 649781 1316747 1613952 2003-04 7 2474261 282364 72149 1186784 454956 513580 689877 1042812 7344244 567103 403439 657535 1343847 1623915 1250496 1155948 239 Table 43: Revenue Expenditure on Total Water Supply and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 1730362 3081922 2483710 1733310 Bihar 929441 1007030 1060822 1077936 Goa 222652 262303 335373 874298 Gujrat 687400 6721345 1024110 1354802 Haryana 761187 1934135 1072819 2575524 Karnataka 1185644 1805437 2210767 3197520 Kerala 832212 883290 1020406 1318686 Madhya Pr. 2763907 3247990 3230626 4159069 Maharashtra 2377731 2643335 3302527 5243830 Orissa 707714 872995 1104517 1766133 Punjab 566030 667175 954816 1848288 Rajasthan 2582195 2733002 3218338 7013261 Tamil Nadu 3276782 2873708 2440523 1629243 Uttar Pr. 1933977 2257017 2564973 4846676 West Bengal 941422 1446427 1298724 4066050 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 1815718 1274692 973333 1851053 3036940 3029099 1952690 2294603 6675724 2035317 2256616 7645750 2163010 2686869 2003-04 7 2393924 1252190 800291 2225329 3534761 3347723 2302998 2470673 9436053 2113575 2582132 7896386 2528419 4065085 2551124 2863432 Table 44: Revenue Expenditure on Total Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 1632143 2863091 2326351 1567083 Bihar 834181 933108 996873 1036353 Goa 204297 243980 303784 753352 Gujrat 563948 6593484 874158 1222858 Haryana 761187 1934135 1072819 2549259 Karnataka 1150174 1762048 2168313 2947278 Kerala 723343 731843 883045 1239335 Madhya Pr. 2664717 3132561 3061401 4078592 Maharashtra 2369111 2636285 3273834 5110574 Orissa 704096 859142 1066271 1706641 Punjab 563576 661913 917198 1811369 Rajasthan 2244919 2384138 2816302 6590220 Tamil Nadu 3196308 2771169 2332326 1559783 Uttar Pr. 1761300 1993714 2285171 4733196 West Bengal 908324 1395873 1229194 3905652 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 1611970 1202563 859823 1672529 3026653 2812999 1781928 2156810 6499158 1984950 2210672 6772388 2056770 2435954 2003-04 7 2227819 1165618 703203 1947763 3502762 3231415 2111202 2211504 9169469 2041087 2565416 6967115 2377808 3527647 2288155 2576544 240 Table 45: Revenue Expenditure on Total Sewage and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 98219 218831 157358 166227 203749 166105 Bihar 95261 73922 63948 41583 72129 86572 Goa 18355 18323 31590 120946 113510 97089 Gujrat 123452 127861 149953 131945 178524 277566 Haryana 0 0 0 26265 10287 31999 Karnataka 35471 43389 42454 250241 216100 116308 Kerala 108869 151447 137361 79351 170762 191796 Madhya Pr. 99190 115429 169225 80478 137794 259169 Maharashtra 8620 7050 28693 133257 176566 266584 Orissa 3618 13854 38246 59493 50367 72488 Punjab 2454 5262 37618 36919 45944 16716 Rajasthan 337276 348865 402037 423041 873362 929271 Tamil Nadu 80474 102539 108197 69460 106240 150611 Uttar Pr. 172677 263303 280801 113481 250915 537438 West Bengal 33098 50554 69529 160398 262969 286888 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 46: Revenue Expenditure on Total Urban Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 358042 559416 415563 402572 598662 1064652 Bihar 354246 402113 358973 196116 215671 97005 Goa 149252 177306 219556 604665 746038 565606 Gujrat 46828 80204 76504 146967 134579 140763 Haryana 30068 372849 141971 357721 846079 1079683 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 0 0 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 275694 330699 243997 345030 611912 559311 Maharashtra 0 0 0 0 0 0 Orissa 145457 145185 177647 601847 711301 686181 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 1401427 1716961 1952153 4006609 4104692 4185911 Tamil Nadu 2093186 1519834 924450 8733 11079 13442 Uttar Pr. 361705 339325 605313 2182376 966853 756203 West Bengal 73691 170764 115375 134450 89711 86159 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 241 Table 47: Revenue Expenditure on Total Rural Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1 Andhra Pr. Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pr. Maharashtra Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pr. West Bengal 1993-94 2 1193927 477435 22757 79100 390796 165586 0 1196154 1696145 383671 477536 818245 967318 1083700 1994-95 3 2216661 520995 23490 63500 1042903 196737 0 1328940 2032336 356873 209015 621021 1065728 1330881 1995-96 4 1798601 623350 27052 60000 378425 392310 0 1403875 2494775 378190 358420 798384 1211399 970210 2001-02 5 1006231 821071 69243 63781 691170 440410 0 2278967 2146528 481371 911645 2410843 1207267 2539604 2002-03 6 833723 829032 70987 77847 862157 222331 0 646993 1528847 621981 1080162 2515529 1287994 1468783 2003-04 7 795313 669051 64854 132500 1169381 280090 0 644284 2833112 696325 859247 2629846 1671369 2771444 250201 461155 368403 1562279 1036960 1215854 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 48: Revenue Expenditure on Total Assistance to Water Supply (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 18800 17515 38319 11692 41137 223000 Bihar 2500 10000 14550 12500 77935 10000 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 6497 7883 6566 23355 23034 35023 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 902137 1426700 1647406 2456051 2535618 2895086 Kerala 723343 731843 883045 842285 774528 1388792 Madhya Pr. 253465 239684 279494 497956 118242 148263 Maharashtra 668886 600806 780934 2905310 4921100 6284046 Orissa 110360 204344 353292 344997 386143 378897 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 25247 46157 65765 172767 148569 148022 Tamil Nadu 113215 185608 196474 343783 572997 692922 Uttar Pr. 0 175 0 230 318 0 West Bengal 15409 13120 8937 496093 145199 63642 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 242 Table 49: Revenue Expenditure on Water Supply - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 1613343 2845576 2288033 1555391 1570833 2004819 Bihar 831681 923108 982323 1023853 1124628 1155618 Goa 204297 243980 303784 753352 859823 703203 Gujrat 557450 6585601 867592 1199503 1649495 1912740 Haryana 761187 1934135 1072819 2549259 3026653 3502762 Karnataka 248037 335348 520907 491227 277381 336329 Kerala 0 0 0 397050 1007400 722410 Madhya Pr. 2411252 2892877 2781907 3580636 2038567 2063241 Maharashtra 1700226 2035480 2492900 2205263 1578058 2885423 Orissa 593736 654798 712979 1361643 1598807 1662190 Punjab 563576 661913 917198 1811369 2210672 2565416 Rajasthan 2219672 2337981 2750537 6417453 6623819 6819093 Tamil Nadu 3083093 2585562 2135852 1216000 1483773 1684886 Uttar Pr. 1761300 1993539 2285171 4732966 2435636 3527647 West Bengal 892914 1382753 1220257 3409559 2142956 2512902 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 50: Revenue Expenditure on Total Assistance to Sewage and Sanitation (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 States 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 53548 190126 128112 116450 48486 55446 Bihar 50 550 0 1992 12400 400 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 28000 18000 28000 65597 117333 217517 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 34971 43389 42454 15572 16156 1000 Kerala 93760 79310 89010 56900 140125 157905 Madhya Pr. 10164 0 8000 3930 32094 18280 Maharashtra 0 0 0 7146 0 4710 Orissa 720 1188 1000 7004 18318 12496 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 30228 18394 11561 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 69444 77436 12700 0 0 101086 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 0 0 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 243 Table 51: Revenue Expenditure on Sewage and Sanitation - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 44671 28705 29246 49777 155263 110659 Bihar 95211 73372 63948 39591 59729 86172 Goa 18355 18323 31590 120946 113510 97089 Gujrat 95452 109861 121953 66348 61191 60049 Haryana 0 0 0 26265 10287 31999 Karnataka 500 0 0 234669 199944 115308 Kerala 15109 72137 48351 22451 30637 33891 Madhya Pr. 89025 115429 161225 76547 105700 240889 Maharashtra 8620 7050 28693 126111 176566 261874 Orissa 2898 12666 37246 52489 32048 59992 Punjab 2454 5262 37618 36919 45944 16716 Rajasthan 337276 348865 402037 423041 873362 929271 Tamil Nadu 50245 84145 96636 69460 106240 150611 Uttar Pr. 103233 185866 268101 113481 250915 436352 West Bengal 33098 50554 69529 160398 262969 286888 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 52: Revenue Expenditure on Total Forestry and Wildlife (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 721935 776580 994822 2070746 Bihar 514141 491696 532258 287892 Goa 37972 42482 43816 87212 Gujrat 524023 616122 719465 1220608 Haryana 467077 469155 530551 656290 Karnataka 1378012 1506747 1706568 3024935 Kerala 480189 674473 717393 1334920 Madhya Pr. 3206407 3435708 3911932 4556215 Maharashtra 1921165 2246857 2392818 2841335 Orissa 577169 544179 577951 885300 Punjab 196290 183982 187251 1002938 Rajasthan 815528 1109410 683563 1301468 Tamil Nadu 415814 451107 505552 853187 Uttar Pr. 983067 909567 1078974 1645253 West Bengal 716641 790919 876320 1627278 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 2005238 300475 90019 1232290 725123 2496782 1408831 4854307 2891842 905483 833446 1300390 866664 1181167 2003-04 7 3169376 319653 109770 1402376 1427647 3356549 1482918 5444997 3354751 828588 970522 1402556 912071 1183250 1301131 1262605 244 Table 53: Revenue Expenditure on Total Forestry (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 599655 664058 867544 1907884 Bihar 498676 467223 491069 227992 Goa 31976 32957 37208 65722 Gujrat 441190 534224 643114 1059174 Haryana 454852 454697 513803 630432 Karnataka 1185610 1311943 1470630 2603544 Kerala 410936 593569 642072 1171100 Madhya Pr. 3120685 3345457 3811662 4276016 Maharashtra 1866454 2187186 2317765 2702069 Orissa 563353 509673 541477 784780 Punjab 171182 153502 153241 998382 Rajasthan 710691 987336 539047 1049133 Tamil Nadu 394403 427842 443362 810061 Uttar Pr. 860014 820477 959842 1548925 West Bengal 601082 649294 745883 1305999 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 1833859 268519 68133 1056094 696399 2027361 1240327 4542009 2750120 777144 831542 1034388 819283 1095661 2003-04 7 2998865 269069 77469 1154737 699906 2881338 1324369 5093448 3030494 671503 958884 1099965 863518 1085727 996573 962480 Table 54: Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Forestry (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 States 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 3328 2789 2259 3949 36594 144577 Bihar 79112 60855 54717 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 84200 95374 97674 172261 174119 222744 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 221350 267776 273104 375923 319039 1195222 Kerala 43181 58103 70066 51275 64242 77188 Madhya Pr. 230266 289984 351532 319973 340344 636453 Maharashtra 115410 134762 125994 19757 20841 23526 Orissa 115821 54628 48162 19368 698 304 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 117120 165513 60569 36967 33361 34808 Tamil Nadu 17062 7938 19107 25581 24350 22077 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 650 0 0 West Bengal 47234 63079 93376 66607 49746 15382 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 245 Table 55: Revenue Expenditure on Forestry - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 596327 661268 865285 1903935 Bihar 419565 406368 436352 227992 Goa 31976 32957 37208 65722 Gujrat 356990 438850 545440 886913 Haryana 454852 454697 513803 630432 Karnataka 964260 1044167 1197526 2227621 Kerala 367755 535467 572005 1119826 Madhya Pr. 2890419 3055473 3460130 3956043 Maharashtra 1751044 2052424 2191771 2682311 Orissa 447532 455045 493316 765412 Punjab 171182 153502 153241 998382 Rajasthan 593571 821822 478478 1012166 Tamil Nadu 377342 419904 424254 784480 Uttar Pr. 860014 820477 959842 1548275 West Bengal 553848 586215 652508 1239391 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 1797265 268519 68133 881974 696399 1708322 1176085 4201665 2729279 776446 831542 1001028 794933 1095661 2003-04 7 2854288 269069 77469 931993 699906 1686116 1247181 4456995 3006968 671199 958884 1065157 841441 1085727 946827 947098 Table 56: Revenue Expenditure on Environmental Forestry (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 States 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 83346 96134 104359 162862 Bihar 15465 24473 41189 59900 Goa 5996 9525 6608 21491 Gujrat 62598 64215 69351 161435 Haryana 12225 14458 16748 25857 Karnataka 127099 130624 139985 421391 Kerala 66753 76904 75321 163820 Madhya Pr. 85722 90251 100270 280199 Maharashtra 54711 59671 75053 139266 Orissa 13816 34506 36474 100520 Punjab 25108 30480 34009 4556 Rajasthan 104837 122075 144516 252336 Tamil Nadu 21411 23265 26593 43126 Uttar Pr. 123052 89090 119132 96327 West Bengal 115559 141625 130437 321280 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 171379 31956 21886 176196 28723 469421 168504 312298 141722 128339 1904 266002 47381 85506 2003-04 7 170511 50584 32301 247639 727741 475211 158549 351549 324257 157085 11638 302591 48553 97523 304557 300125 246 Table 57: Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Environmental Forestry (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 0 0 0 2056 1906 993 Bihar 5688 10352 15449 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 1988 1493 1375 1377 2531 3856 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 10303 47603 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 46480 46508 53108 47738 79560 38758 Maharashtra 0 0 0 0 0 0 Orissa 0 2037 3498 4659 11528 7768 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 0 0 0 1435 570 -28 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 58: Revenue Expenditure on Environmental Forestry - Assistance (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 83346 96134 104359 160806 Bihar 9777 14121 25740 59900 Goa 5996 9525 6608 21491 Gujrat 60610 62722 67976 160057 Haryana 12225 14458 16748 25857 Karnataka 127099 130624 139985 421391 Kerala 66753 76904 75321 163820 Madhya Pr. 39243 43743 47162 232460 Maharashtra 54711 59671 75053 139266 Orissa 13816 32470 32976 95861 Punjab 25108 30480 34009 4556 Rajasthan 104837 122075 144516 252336 Tamil Nadu 21411 23265 26593 43126 Uttar Pr. 123052 89090 119132 96327 West Bengal 115559 141625 130437 319845 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 169473 31956 21886 173665 28723 459118 168504 232738 141722 116811 1904 266002 47381 85506 2003-04 7 169518 50584 32301 243783 727741 427608 158549 312791 324257 149317 11638 302591 48553 97523 303988 300153 247 Table 59: Revenue Expenditure on Total Minor Irrigation (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 629216 514156 607094 1668735 Bihar 1322183 933890 1023079 1246274 Goa 17735 21716 27219 69322 Gujrat 923087 1169808 1235349 1019537 Haryana 218524 472087 89350 200343 Karnataka 443503 506162 454764 859750 Kerala 290936 307146 515380 487112 Madhya Pr. 513331 472640 412738 360168 Maharashtra 1668178 2020619 2376826 2259888 Orissa 514541 474236 617888 791093 Punjab 248444 263934 226021 562651 Rajasthan 519049 524133 533821 681579 Tamil Nadu 386114 519242 460518 290818 Uttar Pr. 3923183 5210191 6097174 2761990 West Bengal 1021816 993988 1122306 2879662 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 1111770 1346352 68895 1224075 548392 826739 555877 348475 2026025 827266 461361 598719 342693 2811817 2003-04 7 715482 1061166 61418 1474217 81767 889074 677902 414723 1945708 753354 441409 589518 380278 2450520 2323805 2410130 Table 60: Revenue Expenditure on Surface Water (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 328968 182927 224751 1333263 781350 371197 Bihar 4087 3936 3103 0 470 95248 Goa 7544 9140 13129 32739 35682 34933 Gujrat 431412 527805 472051 153605 199995 150034 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 149148 180389 194936 288156 280327 268243 Kerala 252114 245929 423077 409546 465288 575678 Madhya Pr. 371026 324091 193551 78946 52579 52146 Maharashtra 364136 361955 520697 253726 137133 219351 Orissa 412677 421682 556789 529712 445961 556637 Punjab 4668 4666 7513 420885 412284 390214 Rajasthan 165960 215914 191059 305365 251001 211031 Tamil Nadu 200588 306210 266991 21158 101405 150169 Uttar Pr. 415894 401800 505396 1210317 1507172 892610 West Bengal 408303 431091 538156 794830 805598 822568 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 248 Table 61: Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Surface Water (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 0 0 0 80790 60455 0 Bihar 0 0 0 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 0 0 0 0 0 0 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 0 0 Kerala 0 0 1860 37970 150 0 Madhya Pr. 73277 71326 23770 1261 4749 9141 Maharashtra 0 0 36370 0 5024 18791 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 4448 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 6624 661 675 0 0 0 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 62: Revenue Expenditure on Ground Water (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 States 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 170911 207050 235187 160101 153590 173591 Bihar 1318096 929954 1019976 1246274 1345882 965918 Goa 4208 4844 5713 10688 11271 11754 Gujrat 336972 420056 513637 426462 436302 438756 Haryana 39074 294787 59350 88843 155249 81767 Karnataka 36241 35697 39808 104867 83943 91400 Kerala 39285 61496 92812 77639 91208 101196 Madhya Pr. 0 0 0 2192 7697 12051 Maharashtra 167546 120719 67584 93589 91851 99594 Orissa 21000 21000 15910 3655 23138 33954 Punjab 177676 209268 173391 141765 49076 51195 Rajasthan 246725 239850 273864 367224 366363 371044 Tamil Nadu 150342 176465 180401 236856 209871 199529 Uttar Pr. 3429794 4808367 5036238 382815 241397 390727 West Bengal 348258 355910 369275 709594 718829 709022 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 249 Table 63: Revenue Expenditure on Assistance to Ground Water (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 0 0 0 4502 4752 4815 Bihar 75425 78455 1618 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 0 0 0 0 0 0 Haryana 4704 0 4 10843 0 0 Karnataka 0 0 0 88 81 90 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 73277 71326 23770 1261 4749 9141 Maharashtra 110472 62710 1743 56 178 242 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 0 0 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. Table 64: Revenue Expenditure on Water Tanks (Rs. in 000’) Years 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 States 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Andhra Pr. 309557 167197 205314 1224246 696741 343629 Bihar 0 0 0 0 0 0 Goa 7544 9140 13129 32739 35682 34933 Gujrat 0 0 0 0 0 0 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 94640 116431 104835 223612 169363 190402 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pr. 270503 249976 169781 77685 47830 43005 Maharashtra 0 0 0 0 0 0 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 172405 283204 235634 21158 101405 150169 Uttar Pr. 0 0 0 32099 60191 32442 West Bengal 12898 8826 16192 25813 25107 25268 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. Note:* implies that the value cannot be calculated because of the average of 1993-96 being zero. 250 Table 65: Revenue Expenditure on Industries (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 311181 432269 640662 420807 Bihar 126479 104883 132780 101353 Goa 1940 2064 2395 11070 Gujarat 76076 147865 146563 2322242 Haryana 65715 73358 76572 120103 Karnataka 757453 647937 548016 620268 Kerala 199608 219272 47688 30788 Madhya Pr. 176714 165272 349747 86508 Maharashtra 147570 860302 1133095 149743 Orissa 4690 32890 20473 8690 Punjab 392829 249455 172263 2439 Rajasthan 403494 618605 900502 178899 Tamil Nadu 126911 339205 217314 61428 Uttar Pr. 84640 85679 104299 474023 West Bengal 244412 393656 363695 988154 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 509997 387070 14406 1235378 194678 444752 171640 118711 1571907 21277 2201 255122 284778 287983 2003-04 7 650422 90142 57356 782228 104245 194006 934765 70114 1290423 9359 2335 303866 150975 1122793 398636 866185 Table 66: Revenue Expenditure on Non Ferrous Mining & Metallurgical Industries (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 32687 36715 45460 80187 Bihar 66657 70316 80982 50821 Goa 2128 2404 2928 4317 Gujarat 59058 67456 110870 100472 Haryana 8247 9339 11180 84557 Karnataka 29812 33197 35974 61516 Kerala 11844 25229 13159 22642 Madhya Pr. 57300 67056 78849 71950 Maharashtra 38874 41734 48280 942984 Orissa 80294 80380 87416 116540 Punjab 4198 4758 5392 7650 Rajasthan 253996 317701 337161 234723 Tamil Nadu 19619 21706 27746 39539 Uttar Pr. 41088 48100 50604 74625 West Bengal 15065 137132 16181 24424 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 82791 49234 4678 175375 87917 57532 24684 74024 406445 128171 7987 273188 36045 77045 2003-04 7 89029 50845 6904 146190 95221 57553 31318 71538 451333 128817 7098 285767 38089 113712 23713 24164 251 Table 67: Revenue Expenditure on Roads & Bridges (TOTAL) (Rs. in 000’) Years States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 2001-02 1 2 3 4 5 Andhra Pr. 1576485 1623467 1701781 4744920 Bihar 1134075 1260557 1274318 1260306 Goa 71770 82813 103366 218377 Gujarat 2350392 2810145 2993392 4335315 Haryana 483343 561082 700961 1421647 Karnataka 1323733 1408615 1497706 3639933 Kerala 910265 917180 1401878 2331036 Madhya Pr. 2658397 3121839 3471866 2450748 Maharashtra -6014 194137 167052 718878 Orissa 858113 1002127 1128641 1301775 Punjab 820771 804991 908349 1071435 Rajasthan 1420291 1430886 1639502 1914787 Tamil Nadu 2354975 2493177 2977569 2631162 Uttar Pr. 2972095 2704151 2656797 5365207 West Bengal 946400 1146763 1438282 2598735 Source: Budget Documents of Different States, Relevant Years. 2002-03 6 4837997 1915957 283812 5136368 899242 3263889 4480496 2240026 9402494 1403406 1459218 2564500 3662008 6747393 2003-04 7 4522639 2020423 340746 5838091 1245617 2774198 4344767 1707633 2550004 1258707 664741 2084922 4492363 6765903 1919305 3165085 252 Table 1: Total State Own Revenue (Tax +Non-tax) in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 383293 422743 412044 488183 711355 796137 900860 Bihar 174840 183599 197327 225083 239040 267156 363756 Goa 18772 22600 27170 30273 36530 35721 45849 Gujrat 394172 474286 532287 606595 659106 761578 816173 Haryana 158891 188786 216896 214312 236863 311962 351761 Karnataka 381234 428931 527393 576784 641187 694304 774437 Kerala 234487 279910 338268 389850 450105 464956 519351 Madhya Pradesh 267711 287061 351819 410350 456431 510848 579522 Maharashtra 769620 945462 1093445 1171497 1371926 1420236 1726495 Orissa 85989 92261 112719 134204 142174 148713 170408 Punjab 214964 259906 265099 273466 304467 326248 394747 Rajasthan 195022 230716 273060 312376 361058 393935 453090 Tamil Nadu 480137 583376 715120 798345 868564 962530 1091893 Uttar Pradesh 413201 487831 546892 630597 699796 791011 940091 West Bengal 291294 373027 413287 425891 451677 477446 510083 Total Major States 4463627.00 5260495.00 6022826.00 6687806.00 7630279.00 8362781.00 9638516.00 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 1069519 1069520 211105 253487 294158 308878 343042 Total All Major States 5533146.00 6330015.00 6233931.00 6941293.00 7924437.00 8671659.00 9981558.00 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 363.0 560.0 412,044.0 488,183.0 983.0 1,129.0 1,387.0 Assam 61,281.0 63,221.0 70,245.0 76,690.0 88,194.0 98,256.0 122,476.0 Himachal Pradesh 25,574.0 29,945.0 34,152.0 41,210.0 47,616.0 57,202.0 62,027.0 Jammu And Kashmir 22,465.0 24,369.0 28,479.0 28,927.0 36,741.0 43,660.0 57,764.0 Manipur 1,852.0 2,380.0 2,790.0 1,420.0 3,573.0 3,074.0 3,995.0 Meghalaya 4,793.0 5,627.0 6,626.0 7,737.0 7,355.0 8,836.0 10,299.0 Mizoram 465.0 458.0 578.0 667.0 787.0 920.0 1,073.0 Nagaland 1,825.0 1,930.0 2,080.0 3,135.0 3,350.0 3,533.0 4,315.0 Sikkim 1,430.0 1,375.0 2,072.0 2,170.0 2,743.0 2,843.0 3,122.0 Tripura 3,712.0 4,347.0 4,799.0 6,050.0 7,164.0 8,413.0 10,174.0 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 123760.00 134212.00 563865.00 656189.00 198506.00 227866.00 276632.00 All States 5656906.00 6464227.00 6797796.00 7597482.00 8122943.00 8899525.00 10258190.00 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Notes: * Compound Growth Rate Calculated for the Period from 1993-94 to 2003-04 (except Chattisgarh, Jharkhand, and Uttaranchal) ** Buoyancy Calculated for the Period from 1993-94 to 2003-04 (except Chattisgarh, Jharkhand, and Uttaranchal) 2000-01 1055192 293475 51480 904682 431148 904267 587026 563958 1972428 218403 489522 529997 1228225 1098000 591757 10919560.00 74968 440062 11434590.00 2001-02 1256366 244237 56934 924681 497243 985327 592342 470232 2128763 246689 482023 567117 1300969 1033018 650513 11436454.00 199313 207595 489675 12333037.00 2002-03 1261755 276471 60219 952046 554968 1043971 730252 617026 2281101 287184 571099 625334 1434170 1276690 704639 12676925.00 232744 227784 532418 13669871.00 2003-04 1380591 336091 71025 1117341 634805 1257012 808877 678876 2516215 330173 614594 724619 1,594,497 1360122 876791 14301629.00 258825 227764 588417 15376635.00 2,069.0 141,293.0 72,841.0 74,805.0 4,907.0 11,862.0 1,443.0 5,621.0 6,582.0 12,558.0 29,529.0 363510.00 11798100.00 3,418.0 156,593.0 91,556.0 85,754.0 5,197.0 13,597.0 1,912.0 5,244.0 8,039.0 15,850.0 89,469.0 476629.00 12809666.00 3654 193451 88,753.0 97,565.0 6,516.0 14,486.0 2797 6189 10553 18,294.0 102169 544427.00 14214298.00 4312 207031 98433 115,194.0 6,917.0 17,769.0 3385 6855 10800 22,146.0 122596 615438.00 15992073.00 253 Table 2: State Own Non-tax Revenue in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 Andhra Pradesh 135,143 153,031 160,547 162,472 178,821 184,696 Bihar 88,684 97,482 91,453 106,134 38,986 114,596 Goa 13,612 14,962 40,187 34,732 58,220 65,058 Gujrat 139,878 148,811 160,117 157,274 222,097 276,649 Haryana 134,055 347,341 218,681 313,267 263,110 151,802 Karnataka 73,357 84,767 123,542 134,231 126,440 146,992 Kerala 32,322 39,635 53,549 51,380 55,210 55,766 Madhya Pradesh 140,373 161,521 177,814 197,494 201,855 178,199 Maharashtra 238,301 290,285 277,539 375,488 364,089 357,270 Orissa 41,545 63,423 62,823 48,178 54,093 55,749 Punjab 41,406 200,362 177,737 194,480 235,653 150,735 Rajasthan 118,137 129,557 225,675 136,112 136,242 135,339 Tamil Nadu 70,389 77,266 85,845 88,545 112,187 115,670 Uttar Pradesh 171,750 188,933 239,941 131,849 129,171 147,506 West Bengal 30,861 34,201 32,748 41,745 44,949 38,450 Total Major States 1,469,813 2,031,577 2,128,198 2,173,381 2,221,123 2,174,477 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 1,669 9,963 6,314 5,574 16,952 18,796 Total All Major States 1,471,482 2,041,540 2,134,512 2,178,955 2,238,075 2,193,273 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 8,517 8,054 8,108 6,498 5,473 6,454 Assam 34,899 32,650 33,560 32,213 38,122 45,197 Himachal Pradesh 12,061 13,274 11,735 14,686 22,204 20,550 Jammu And Kashmir 13,505 15,577 15,798 15,498 27,261 28,326 Manipur 2,797 5,002 4,549 5,915 4,057 3,152 Meghalaya 2,840 3,864 6,692 4,747 2,985 5,146 Mizoram 3,122 3,447 4,586 4,642 4,584 3,616 Nagaland 2,392 6,786 3,410 4,104 4,532 4,492 Sikkim 2,755 33,216 62,673 82,934 92,983 102,092 Tripura 2,513 2,596 3,852 4,066 3,487 4,483 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 85,401 124,466 154,963 175,303 205,688 223,508 All States 1,556,883 2,166,006 2,289,475 2,354,258 2,443,763 2,416,781 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 1999-00 244,155 175,890 63,337 291,927 125,906 161,128 53,072 246,897 393,687 71,648 236,146 157,377 135,685 201,174 58,722 2,616,751 2000-01 274,291 80,587 79,614 334,915 143,939 165,998 65,908 172,433 559,626 68,547 293,523 168,798 171,078 194,465 121,453 2,895,175 28,823 39,785 2,656,536 6,701 44,492 105,624 40,527 4,265 8,386 4,140 4,901 104,275 7,619 330,930 2,987,466 54,835 2,978,833 2001-02 291,764 36,094 113,608 376,094 166,607 109,342 54,338 160,168 465,507 69,175 296,045 150,846 155,673 178,707 77,588 2,701,556 72,238 95943 87,606 2,957,343 2002-03 352,942 32,340 103,917 399,558 180,785 127,766 67,777 163,548 451,747 96,117 403,557 156,900 186,062 191,349 65,433 2,979,798 95,655 95995 82,957 3,254,405 2003-04 360,465 44,559 72,474 327,196 222,306 295,838 80,698 147,982 354,894 109,454 466,553 207,165 209,378 228,208 60,584 3,187,754 112,441 115094 95,034 3,510,323 6,370 52,677 17,697 23,943 4,166 8,666 4,037 4,394 28,903 9,451 6,313 166,617 3,145,450 7,091 53,320 19,833 30,102 2,873 9,407 4,487 4,836 112,821 9,764 16,213 270,747 3,228,090 7,630 69,297 17,549 33,466 5,649 9,279 5,263 4,393 131,585 9,872 37,485 331,468 3,585,873 12,057 94,581 29,176 35,435 4,932 12,895 5,801 6,091 53,729 16,778 37,059 308,534 3,818,857 254 Table 3: Interest Receipts (in Rs. Lakh) Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 Andhra Pradesh 70,553 76,843 71,766 82,408 90,353 114,551 Bihar 3,257 2,893 2,010 5,648 8,780 13,599 Goa 270 247 341 250 276 445 Gujrat 77,753 82,169 85,562 81,614 120,721 159,269 Haryana 11,653 47,609 25,693 23,756 23,707 18,372 Karnataka 33,777 40,264 69,575 67,461 56,252 66,974 Kerala 2,760 3,776 10,032 5,573 5,348 7,095 Madhya Pradesh 21,596 21,311 14,102 26,987 22,325 14,748 Maharashtra 92,861 117,708 127,121 203,453 169,414 165,389 Orissa 8,769 5,366 13,869 1,344 1,869 1,962 Punjab 7,400 8,154 8,705 146,414 98,284 10,486 Rajasthan 61,294 42,287 50,156 62,490 59,813 62,879 Tamil Nadu 27,524 27,879 34,283 34,901 48,625 38,495 Uttar Pradesh 35,478 37,343 46,377 47,897 48,434 42,799 West Bengal 7,121 8,901 5,094 11,275 10,489 4,864 Total Major States 462,066 522,750 564,686 801,471 764,690 721,927 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 535 2,006 713 542 13,283 13,901 Total All Major States 462,601 524,756 565,399 802,013 777,973 735,828 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 409 324 590 653 524 607 Assam 238 215 244 215 214 218 Himachal Pradesh 322 923 2,537 2,435 1,302 940 Jammu And Kashmir 8,178 9,579 9,290 9,997 10,010 8,817 Manipur 190 92 120 102 91 82 Meghalaya 177 169 247 478 408 598 Mizoram 32 42 305 46 42 61 Nagaland 145 150 200 214 200 245 Sikkim 91 35 113 182 6 26 Tripura 161 166 201 760 213 360 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 9,943 11,695 13,847 15,082 13,010 11,954 All States 472,544 536,451 579,246 817,095 790,983 747,782 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 1999-00 142,008 32,854 504 176,454 20,223 80,167 3,731 25,707 172,416 1,946 53,502 67,042 34,679 47,668 11,008 869,909 2000-01 146,566 13,280 285 192,982 23,623 72,118 3,681 18,456 316,163 1,309 70,611 58,955 40,364 52,517 67,360 1,078,270 347 30,077 899,986 423 247 15,951 10,255 69 838 83 300 51 1,162 29,379 929,365 47,728 1,126,345 2001-02 153,855 8,908 217 159,430 33,287 14,192 3,108 24,659 184,560 2,527 55,198 58,378 50,197 54,349 12,290 815,155 4,911 5000 78,982 904,048 2002-03 171,740 2,903 213 168,488 33,427 3,436 3,586 3,205 177,727 7,609 91,337 60,704 56,871 51,538 10,274 843,058 9,565 5603 74,142 932,368 2003-04 181,853 2,998 221 89,712 47,801 11,134 3,240 1,922 35,691 16,438 146,405 68,512 53,253 65,808 11,011 735,999 12,246 5603 86,883 840,731 899 427 1,500 10,499 75 926 312 300 448 1,849 189 17,424 1,143,769 635 309 767 12,405 100 526 145 310 602 358 315 16,472 920,520 597 307 997 13,243 61 466 244 172 717 582 392 17,778 950,146 845 589 1,135 13,107 139 562 327 561 274 367 3,022 20,928 861,659 255 Table 4: Dividends and Profits States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 Andhra Pradesh 25 395 478 768 534 942 Bihar 29 31 0 5648 0 0 Goa 39 47 36 52 67 44 Gujrat 2126 1408 3400 2277 1449 2238 Haryana 95 702 314 453 238 221 Karnataka 451 652 323 529 544 627 Kerala 393 462 581 392 592 713 Madhya Pradesh 80 79 161 281 155 100 Maharashtra 273 379 416 927 933 601 Orissa 61 -2 215 36 320 28 Punjab 314 785 461 543 299 149 Rajasthan 170 91 594 619 861 800 Tamil Nadu 1441 786 2838 2220 1845 2429 Uttar Pradesh 483 932 346 680 576 619 West Bengal 178 100 40 53 185 44 Total Major States 6158 6847 10203 15478 8598 9555 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 0 285 75 695 444 482 Total All Major States 6158 7132 10278 16173 9042 10037 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 1 2 1 1 0 3 Assam 8 5 3 37 35 2 Himachal Pradesh 19 37 20 58 55 53 Jammu And Kashmir 0 100 0 123 123 391 Manipur 1 2 0 2 0 0 Meghalaya 1 2 3 0 3 3 Mizoram 0 1 0 0 0 0 Nagaland 0 0 0 0 0 0 Sikkim 15 67 20 138 159 123 Tripura 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 45 216 47 359 375 575 All States 6203 7348 10325 16532 9417 10612 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 1999-00 291 35 33 2703 778 624 1001 181 396 11114 915 529 4195 589 123 23507 2000-01 202 5 24 2607 181 275 1264 44 395 3790 233 557 3653 874 318 14422 0 441 23948 0 44 59 773 0 60 0 0 72 0 1008 24956 870 15292 2001-02 57 9 44 2752 40 514 526 164 453 876 109 478 3345 639 377 10383 500 100 717 11700 2002-03 134 9 19 4203 173 1493 961 409 186 15222 91 826 2599 784 138 27247 2557 112 719 30635 2003-04 4868 1 3 2989 411 1690 2003 842 1893 13806 182 244 2720 788 50 32490 3482 112 603 36687 0 73 61 0 0 1 0 0 2 0 2 139 15431 0 83 89 960 0 11 0 0 1 0 2 1146 12846 0 593 61 1289 1 1 0 0 176 0 4 2125 32760 0 688 50 1547 0 18 0 0 74 0 4 2381 39068 256 Table 5: Revenue from General Services in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 5,286 7,399 10,012 11,212 9,230 8,937 10,176 Bihar 2,347 3,489 1,471 2,075 13,169 10,247 17,292 Goa 386 426 22,799 14,732 34,694 31,437 26,332 Gujrat 5,334 7,547 11,344 10,876 25,439 36,541 20,729 Haryana 86,272 259,904 152,098 239,093 180,981 70,605 39,585 Karnataka 6,949 9,734 9,956 12,342 14,229 12,711 15,183 Kerala 8,906 10,820 13,445 15,788 19,000 18,567 21,064 Madhya Pradesh 8,400 10,585 9,359 10,795 13,421 11,078 21,213 Maharashtra 23,008 23,719 30,147 28,810 31,840 28,239 43,398 Orissa 4,149 4,696 8,043 4,877 5,408 5,336 7,062 Punjab 6,754 160,766 139,457 16,717 105,287 106,928 146,366 Rajasthan 26,267 50,946 132,679 24,757 22,353 14,564 27,488 Tamil Nadu 7,345 10,703 11,185 11,623 16,649 18,681 28,040 Uttar Pradesh 85,521 103,410 131,869 19,369 19,174 33,343 33,337 West Bengal 5,855 6,786 8,772 11,052 14,352 13,305 16,092 Total Major States 282,779 670,930 692,636 434,118 525,226 420,519 473,357 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 806 6,554 4,141 2,612 2,216 2,666 5,340 Total All Major States 283,585 677,484 696,777 436,730 527,442 423,185 478,697 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 2,452 2,096 819 789 1,014 1,056 1,350 Assam 1,934 1,902 2,521 1,872 3,357 5,811 5,204 Himachal Pradesh 1,694 1,174 2,366 2,714 3,083 3,174 5,576 Jammu And Kashmir 758 817 965 1,086 9,111 2,412 2,448 Manipur 892 3,074 2,329 3,381 2,309 1,407 1,163 Meghalaya 677 597 1,711 1,928 768 863 1,123 Mizoram 1,177 1,804 1,929 2,482 2,544 1,697 1,126 Nagaland 405 1,357 1,020 980 1,190 1,308 965 Sikkim 874 31,478 60,498 80,116 90,558 99,913 101,180 Tripura 275 415 820 794 578 858 1,104 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 11,138 44,714 74,978 96,142 114,512 118,499 121,239 All States 294,723 722,198 771,755 532,872 641,954 541,684 599,936 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 15,236 16,918 38,058 22,343 47,972 18,980 25,302 18,465 54,684 6,936 183,242 38,256 31,711 26,172 20,514 564,789 861 3,538 569,188 2001-02 18,613 8,384 61,244 79,639 51,834 16,665 21,706 23,045 75,675 6,831 202,764 17,181 32,609 33,360 16,252 665,802 3,061 1842 4,008 674,713 2002-03 17,711 9,946 37,362 56,214 64,178 34,926 26,195 22,602 68,613 6,008 272,355 17,609 38,796 31,477 17,644 721,636 8,324 2064 4,518 736,542 2003-04 27,444 12,073 906 29,803 67,835 178,382 30,704 12,571 97,660 5,620 259,324 47,096 34,099 28,438 17,895 849,850 9,893 2998 4,145 866,886 699 4,270 3,313 1,994 575 798 826 671 25,008 597 809 39,560 608,748 745 1,697 3,206 2,244 338 1,052 919 729 108,187 807 1,831 121,755 796,468 1,093 2,482 3,692 2,369 631 1,511 1,764 667 126,318 660 2,419 143,606 880,148 2,085 3,435 3,708 3,346 435 1,654 1,440 735 48,833 980 3,706 70,357 937,243 257 Table 6: Revenue from Social Services in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 7,101 6,374 6,185 6,772 7,259 7,409 28,140 Bihar 3,147 3,408 2,932 2,425 9,225 7,839 5,941 Goa 1,294 1,372 1,920 2,120 2,373 4,767 4,681 Gujrat 6,993 6,210 6,914 7,740 9,974 10,579 11,998 Haryana 4,022 4,137 5,230 7,349 13,937 12,825 14,095 Karnataka 5,303 5,352 10,225 10,299 16,040 10,945 10,697 Kerala 4,188 4,588 6,094 4,726 6,216 6,614 6,725 Madhya Pradesh 5,148 4,712 4,618 5,679 7,786 6,779 9,353 Maharashtra 14,889 15,729 16,406 17,437 23,066 26,396 31,464 Orissa 2,807 2,936 2,973 3,512 3,989 4,202 5,635 Punjab 4,564 5,008 3,918 5,225 5,237 5,103 6,999 Rajasthan 7,827 10,142 11,641 11,156 14,182 15,877 16,265 Tamil Nadu 8,773 9,754 11,434 12,910 15,532 20,094 22,964 Uttar Pradesh 6,429 8,197 10,156 14,254 16,603 22,177 29,713 West Bengal 5,910 4,890 4,764 4,239 6,061 6,903 8,526 Total Major States 88,395 92,809 105,410 115,843 157,480 168,509 213,196 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 192 720 825 644 691 1,026 2,486 Total All Major States 88,587 93,529 106,235 116,487 158,171 169,535 215,682 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 129 140 89 108 142 165 118 Assam 675 611 682 640 665 913 949 Himachal Pradesh 819 947 936 1,103 7,984 4,815 2,516 Jammu And Kashmir 263 278 297 375 583 808 885 Manipur 176 269 466 287 257 135 591 Meghalaya 100 104 144 267 136 115 119 Mizoram 216 216 263 277 235 262 332 Nagaland 84 90 99 118 127 136 569 Sikkim 32 33 50 42 41 95 82 Tripura 160 243 249 257 206 246 775 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 2,654 2,931 3,275 3,474 10,376 7,690 6,936 All States 91,241 96,460 109,510 119,961 168,547 177,225 222,618 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 18,959 5,121 5,073 24,235 13,262 12,213 7,678 7,483 30,411 6,275 7,327 19,485 22,759 32,563 8,016 220,860 557 1,188 222,605 2001-02 21,358 6,168 6,251 26,365 14,614 14,366 8,182 7,355 33,661 7,192 7,726 20,668 23,600 28,324 10,749 236,579 2,491 2825 1,904 243,799 2002-03 32,500 5,732 6,806 24,176 15,469 18,613 10,627 8,964 33,028 7,543 9,561 19,552 26,159 35,963 8,570 263,263 3,183 3165 2,264 271,875 2003-04 24,923 12,502 7,591 19,506 26,634 12,326 12,764 8,123 38,177 6,462 10,598 25,300 47,670 35,741 9,461 297,778 2,371 5164 2,230 307,543 125 1,154 2,996 1,139 686 156 419 599 159 469 633 8,535 231,140 175 1,323 3,351 1,553 310 168 481 630 183 1,426 2,404 12,004 255,803 417 1,308 3,303 2,267 372 194 475 467 235 1,313 3,357 13,708 285,583 523 4,996 6,214 2,845 492 204 567 390 262 802 3,454 20,749 328,292 258 Table 7: Revenue from Education, Sports, Art and Culture in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 3005 2271 2234 2326 2824 2875 23399 Bihar 527 527 299 324 5660 2230 400 Goa 38 44 97 87 119 148 222 Gujrat 1809 1538 1973 2082 2329 3090 3228 Haryana 1207 1236 1354 1832 1843 1902 2121 Karnataka 1767 1579 1503 1468 1599 1727 2133 Kerala 2176 2832 2908 2616 3048 3534 3918 Madhya Pradesh 501 633 747 1156 1095 1096 2615 Maharashtra 2323 2853 3140 3464 2938 3612 2569 Orissa 952 1123 1158 1126 1265 1249 1511 Punjab 571 603 673 1036 865 881 1289 Rajasthan 387 671 1195 1391 1701 819 771 Tamil Nadu 2482 2955 2968 3157 3313 3829 4486 Uttar Pradesh 2994 4123 4938 5465 9589 10134 13763 West Bengal 440 605 1378 383 606 567 687 Total Major States 21179 23593 26565 27913 38794 37693 63112 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 91 382 160 155 171 250 385 Total All Major States 21270 23975 26725 28068 38965 37943 63497 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 76 102 55 53 63 77 56 Assam 126 122 154 149 134 190 186 Himachal Pradesh 219 266 241 268 613 974 1048 Jammu And Kashmir 19 22 21 23 23 67 60 Manipur 54 60 165 74 62 42 82 Meghalaya 39 47 33 57 53 35 42 Mizoram 44 20 21 19 25 28 34 Nagaland 18 20 21 22 23 24 25 Sikkim 6 12 11 9 10 11 12 Tripura 67 79 112 60 23 34 26 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 668 750 834 734 1029 1482 1571 All States 21938 24725 27559 28802 39994 39425 65068 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 11684 1874 155 3830 2178 3977 4498 1324 3176 1991 1042 2453 5375 17724 1763 63044 91 384 63519 2001-02 9245 400 208 3935 2140 3177 5356 1299 3302 2498 1388 3427 6579 13766 3961 60681 251 481 544 61957 2002-03 14767 400 317 6750 2813 4332 6341 1039 5833 2431 1439 1733 8950 25535 1728 84408 467 539 654 86068 2003-04 7121 5839 1151 6366 3266 3007 8186 908 6612 1200 2130 7881 12258 22768 2120 90813 455 541 669 92478 72 220 1320 110 216 55 31 26 48 71 422 2591 66110 69 277 1528 55 103 62 41 27 41 435 1796 4434 66391 63 292 1462 69 113 75 42 15 41 110 2267 4549 90617 153 3800 4185 88 97 80 69 19 88 128 2128 10835 103313 259 Table 8: Revenue from Medical, Public Health and Family Welfare in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 Andhra Pradesh 1,937 1,473 1,371 1,415 2,204 2,356 2,524 2,501 Bihar 1,064 1,257 917 811 1,147 1,485 2,062 1,601 Goa 150 157 219 222 292 445 374 477 Gujrat 3,240 2,774 2,841 2,557 4,628 3,918 4,171 4,959 Haryana 1,250 900 1,031 1,390 2,073 1,737 2,479 2,355 Karnataka 2,271 2,338 2,145 2,181 3,147 3,416 3,247 2,910 Kerala 1,539 1,145 2,359 1,176 2,201 2,151 1,892 2,071 Madhya Pradesh 975 894 1,031 949 1,545 1,126 1,597 958 Maharashtra 5,813 6,372 5,722 6,159 8,074 8,375 8,728 7,831 Orissa 530 501 359 639 635 814 1,127 1,012 Punjab 2,104 2,106 1,175 1,721 2,126 1,559 3,007 3,001 Rajasthan 1,538 1,043 1,680 981 1,715 1,496 1,247 1,620 Tamil Nadu 2,744 2,847 3,381 3,064 4,211 6,330 7,170 6,183 Uttar Pradesh 1,591 1,976 1,507 2,173 2,578 4,381 5,262 3,255 West Bengal 4,303 3,348 2,260 2,868 3,896 3,545 6,215 4,606 Total Major States 31,049 29,131 27,998 28,306 40,472 43,134 51,102 45,340 Chattisgarh 25 Jharkhand NCT Delhi 49 143 152 168 284 398 466 525 Total All Major States 31,098 29,274 28,150 28,474 40,756 43,532 51,568 45,890 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 5 6 5 6 21 26 8 9 Assam 297 278 254 228 274 355 457 466 Himachal Pradesh 225 220 175 351 235 370 437 510 Jammu And Kashmir 116 146 157 190 227 306 327 472 Manipur 18 17 43 50 20 16 81 26 Meghalaya 28 21 47 142 37 32 33 34 Mizoram 12 15 15 14 27 15 20 27 Nagaland 5 5 5 6 7 9 9 10 Sikkim 14 9 21 11 10 42 14 37 Tripura 23 38 42 35 38 69 95 111 Uttaranchal 66 Total Special category States 743 755 764 1,033 896 1,240 1,481 1,768 All States 31,841 30,029 28,914 29,507 41,652 44,772 53,049 47,658 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2001-02 5,505 2,700 467 4,763 2,872 6,059 1,987 1,655 11,178 1,027 2,919 2,482 6,607 3,163 4,607 57,991 333 591 872 59,787 2002-03 3,867 2,200 694 3,942 2,883 5,789 2,822 2,102 9,848 1,129 4,144 2,269 8,389 4,246 4,896 59,220 254 662 1,242 61,378 2003-04 2,953 1,922 730 4,282 3,211 3,306 2,767 1,216 10,540 755 4,158 1,640 6,634 4,319 4,800 53,233 260 809 1,098 55,400 10 723 347 684 35 41 39 11 35 133 364 2,422 62,209 13 591 323 822 35 55 40 15 36 161 546 2,637 64,015 27 423 343 956 32 62 32 7 44 346 434 2,706 58,106 260 Table 9: Revenue from Housing in Rs.lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 Andhra Pradesh 127 116 106 115 109 122 Bihar 105 110 91 114 126 116 Goa 19 16 15 16 19 19 Gujrat 298 311 329 439 491 642 Haryana 84 95 97 105 109 109 Karnataka 460 441 491 502 554 807 Kerala 86 105 108 147 126 125 Madhya Pradesh 432 408 432 412 431 431 Maharashtra 1,587 963 1,442 970 896 1,784 Orissa 487 505 510 523 569 719 Punjab 57 60 57 59 74 145 Rajasthan 104 113 118 134 147 242 Tamil Nadu 908 1,032 1,013 1,075 1,107 1,837 Uttar Pradesh 418 647 593 498 597 331 West Bengal 413 416 416 563 670 729 Total Major States 5,585 5,338 5,818 5,672 6,025 8,158 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 30 101 351 164 110 152 Total All Major States 5,615 5,439 6,169 5,836 6,135 8,310 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 9 7 6 9 8 9 Assam 65 70 77 68 67 125 Himachal Pradesh 50 54 51 58 6,586 2,903 Jammu And Kashmir 39 36 23 47 112 43 Manipur 16 40 28 31 37 26 Meghalaya 13 15 29 15 16 18 Mizoram 35 24 26 28 32 29 Nagaland 28 28 30 32 34 36 Sikkim 0 0 0 0 0 15 Tripura 16 28 30 15 38 16 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 271 302 300 303 6,930 3,220 All States 5,886 5,741 6,469 6,139 13,065 11,530 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 1999-00 135 150 19 1,133 119 785 140 482 1,049 1,047 235 251 2,558 1,537 739 10,379 2000-01 167 120 23 1,071 125 923 287 1,078 1,089 1,156 170 305 2,553 541 773 10,381 78 119 10,498 8 112 111 55 43 19 30 454 17 51 900 11,398 143 10,602 2001-02 154 116 26 709 128 1,050 183 1,301 1,868 1,170 168 319 2,298 792 793 11,075 163 50 168 11,456 2002-03 2,400 116 21 1,072 147 6,708 176 1,365 1,668 1,245 175 590 2,227 1,005 994 19,909 168 56 174 20,307 2003-04 9,838 141 23 1,052 131 3,814 168 1,401 2,073 1,217 184 416 2,432 1,040 1,112 25,042 169 56 162 25,429 8 120 182 79 58 17 33 477 18 67 43 1,102 11,704 9 152 203 93 100 18 36 501 18 82 116 1,328 12,784 9 193 173 331 75 18 38 225 17 80 140 1,299 21,606 9 192 164 136 93 20 37 219 18 88 156 1,132 26,561 261 Table 10: Revenue from Urban Development in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 117 213 358 468 103 164 107 Bihar 22 23 79 1 41 1 100 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 Gujrat 479 189 443 501 543 521 627 Haryana 310 495 720 1,333 7,068 5,929 5,747 Karnataka 30 4 4,899 4,736 5,299 80 140 Kerala 177 259 445 263 308 296 109 Madhya Pradesh 211 76 44 187 55 102 63 Maharashtra 1,238 994 1,622 2,299 3,380 1,116 3,587 Orissa 30 18 14 9 8 7 13 Punjab 70 140 125 208 51 214 175 Rajasthan 23 21 13 71 0 54 49 Tamil Nadu 60 64 68 34 51 42 42 Uttar Pradesh 5 9 61 3 27 4 67 West Bengal 24 27 31 30 122 107 160 Total Major States 2,796 2,532 8,922 10,143 17,056 8,639 10,986 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 1 0 0 3 0 0 1,293 Total All Major States 2,797 2,532 8,922 10,146 17,056 8,639 12,279 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 0 0 0 0 4 0 0 Assam 1 2 10 2 0 0 1 Himachal Pradesh 3 1 14 3 5 18 15 Jammu And Kashmir 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Manipur 0 38 10 0 0 0 0 Meghalaya 1 1 4 34 1 2 1 Mizoram 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Nagaland 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Sikkim 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tripura 0 4 0 1 0 0 0 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 5 46 38 40 10 20 17 All States 2,802 2,578 8,960 10,186 17,066 8,659 12,296 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 302 100 0 729 4,457 233 108 159 1,932 10 389 85 130 3,447 44 12,125 3 2 12,130 2001-02 415 22 2 620 5,338 100 47 121 1,873 16 72 -19 79 669 88 9,443 9 9 86 9,547 2002-03 1,307 22 9 2,662 5,074 112 91 146 2,066 12 254 68 133 330 70 12,356 99 10 33 12,498 2003-04 446 1 2 2,255 14,355 231 166 123 5,043 2 200 95 19,465 1,215 62 43,661 142 10 18 43,831 5 23 21 2 0 22 0 0 0 0 0 73 12,203 0 1 33 0 0 1 0 0 0 29 0 64 9,611 233 3 75 0 0 7 0 131 0 1 0 450 12,948 211 2 125 0 0 1 0 0 0 4 0 343 44,174 262 Table 11: Revenue from Water Supply and Sanitation in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 0 0 517 730 227 354 352 Bihar 0 0 134 130 24 209 275 Goa 0 0 1,550 1,764 1,908 4,119 4,021 Gujrat 0 0 63 146 102 57 52 Haryana 0 0 1,305 1,823 1,929 2,098 2,532 Karnataka 0 0 160 124 111 295 204 Kerala 0 0 25 48 65 86 68 Madhya Pradesh 0 0 945 766 1,026 881 1,231 Maharashtra 0 0 344 514 726 1,176 817 Orissa 0 0 640 961 1,260 1,220 1,406 Punjab 0 0 182 829 784 962 975 Rajasthan 0 0 7,576 7,845 9,679 12,161 12,572 Tamil Nadu 0 0 237 464 290 315 566 Uttar Pradesh 0 0 8 10 200 15 97 West Bengal 0 0 152 85 82 117 70 Total Major States 0 0 13,838 16,239 18,413 24,065 25,238 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total All Major States 0 0 13,838 16,239 18,413 24,065 25,238 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 0 0 12 17 19 27 19 Assam 0 0 26 18 25 46 46 Himachal Pradesh 0 0 339 298 370 439 594 Jammu And Kashmir 0 0 84 102 208 310 386 Manipur 0 0 39 80 87 44 62 Meghalaya 0 0 23 13 17 14 21 Mizoram 0 0 195 203 138 167 233 Nagaland 0 0 30 50 55 58 64 Sikkim 0 0 12 11 14 15 27 Tripura 0 0 11 101 35 63 508 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 0 0 771 893 968 1,183 1,960 All States 0 0 14,609 17,132 19,381 25,248 27,198 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 1,162 184 4,359 44 2,773 62 156 1,115 388 1,732 1,519 13,889 658 1 314 28,356 56 0 28,412 2001-02 909 207 5,314 50 2,870 186 128 1,151 509 1,896 1,531 13,983 885 16 367 30,002 119 89 0 30,210 2002-03 1,635 213 5,571 122 3,582 115 268 1,938 270 2,329 2,197 14,300 826 0 301 33,667 430 100 0 34,197 2003-04 617 44 5,466 101 3,731 61 274 1,964 1,042 2,416 2,681 14,630 675 290 630 34,622 522 674 0 35,818 22 74 513 414 66 21 287 67 38 122 0 1,624 30,036 79 33 848 700 67 26 349 70 43 605 0 2,820 33,030 93 34 976 1,000 144 23 339 63 73 88 0 2,833 37,030 111 359 1,104 1,610 246 29 392 80 74 195 332 4,532 40,350 263 Table 12: Revenue from Economic Services in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 Andhra Pradesh 52,178 62,020 72,106 61,312 71,445 52,857 Bihar 79,904 87,661 85,040 90,338 7,812 82,911 Goa 11,623 12,870 15,091 17,578 20,810 28,365 Gujrat 47,617 51,464 52,886 54,766 64,511 68,019 Haryana 32,013 34,989 35,346 42,616 44,247 49,779 Karnataka 26,877 28,765 33,463 43,600 39,375 55,735 Kerala 16,075 19,989 23,397 24,901 24,054 22,777 Madhya Pradesh 105,149 124,834 149,574 153,752 158,167 145,493 Maharashtra 107,270 132,747 103,447 124,858 138,834 136,641 Orissa 25,759 50,427 37,723 38,408 42,506 44,220 Punjab 22,374 25,649 25,196 25,581 26,546 28,069 Rajasthan 22,579 26,091 30,605 37,090 39,033 41,219 Tamil Nadu 25,304 28,143 26,105 26,891 29,536 35,969 Uttar Pradesh 43,837 39,048 51,187 49,566 44,314 48,140 West Bengal 11,797 13,524 14,078 15,126 13,861 13,334 Total Major States 630,356 738,221 755,244 806,383 765,051 853,528 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 136 398 560 1,081 315 721 Total All Major States 630,492 738,619 755,804 807,464 765,366 854,249 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 5,526 5,492 6,609 4,947 3,793 4,623 Assam 32,044 29,916 30,110 29,449 33,851 38,253 Himachal Pradesh 9,207 10,193 5,876 8,376 9,780 11,568 Jammu And Kashmir 4,306 4,803 5,246 3,917 7,434 15,898 Manipur 1,538 1,565 1,634 2,143 1,400 1,528 Meghalaya 1,885 2,992 4,587 2,074 1,670 3,567 Mizoram 1,697 1,384 2,089 1,837 1,763 1,596 Nagaland 1,758 5,189 2,091 2,792 3,015 2,803 Sikkim 1,743 1,603 1,992 2,456 2,219 1,935 Tripura 1,917 1,772 2,582 2,255 2,490 3,019 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 61,621 64,909 62,816 60,246 67,415 84,790 All States 692,113 803,528 818,620 867,710 832,781 939,039 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 1999-00 63,540 119,768 31,787 80,040 51,225 54,457 20,551 190,442 146,012 45,891 28,363 46,053 45,804 89,855 22,973 1,036,761 2000-01 93,328 45,263 36,174 92,745 58,901 62,412 27,983 127,982 157,971 50,236 32,110 51,545 72,591 82,268 25,247 1,016,756 27,058 1,438 1,038,199 4,810 38,048 81,522 26,166 2,442 6,246 2,598 3,067 2,890 4,578 172,367 1,210,566 1,511 1,045,325 2001-02 97,881 12,625 45,852 107,905 66,832 63,605 20,816 104,944 171,157 51,748 30,248 54,141 45,921 62,033 37,917 973,625 61,275 86176 1,995 1,123,071 2002-03 130,857 13,750 59,517 146,433 67,538 69,298 26,408 128,367 172,193 59,734 30,213 58,209 61,638 71,584 28,806 1,124,545 72,026 85051 1,314 1,282,936 2003-04 121,377 16,985 63,753 185,175 79,625 92,306 31,987 124,522 181,447 67,128 50,044 66,013 71,632 97,429 22,165 1,271,588 84,449 101217 1,173 1,458,427 4,647 46,753 9,827 10,311 2,830 6,785 2,476 2,824 3,286 6,536 4,680 100,955 1,146,280 5,536 49,907 12,420 12,940 2,125 7,650 2,942 3,167 3,848 7,173 11,659 119,367 1,242,438 5,523 64,606 9,496 14,298 4,584 7,107 2,780 3,087 4,139 7,316 31,313 154,249 1,437,185 8,604 84,872 18,069 14,590 3,866 10,457 3,467 4,405 4,286 14,629 26,873 194,118 1,652,545 264 Table 13: Revenue from Forestry and Wildlife in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 7,044 10,286 14,476 11,589 10,735 10,060 8,461 Bihar 7,000 7,700 2,853 2,365 0 1,824 3,177 Goa 115 139 139 157 114 71 93 Gujrat 1,523 1,675 1,472 1,565 1,967 1,603 2,207 Haryana 1,185 1,336 1,780 2,160 1,743 1,917 2,491 Karnataka 9,198 9,508 10,609 11,335 11,381 10,735 9,488 Kerala 10,296 13,688 16,077 16,200 14,491 12,103 10,988 Madhya Pradesh 49,212 52,315 57,384 55,961 62,585 50,760 31,528 Maharashtra 13,605 19,280 14,398 14,697 14,738 13,031 13,474 Orissa 9,947 11,880 6,826 7,621 7,329 8,730 9,579 Punjab 528 515 689 531 766 652 1,079 Rajasthan 1,129 1,365 1,360 1,889 1,860 1,791 2,298 Tamil Nadu 5,527 6,481 5,797 5,273 4,366 6,400 13,008 Uttar Pradesh 12,116 8,189 10,108 10,451 11,326 12,591 16,052 West Bengal 3,244 4,461 4,427 4,701 3,316 1,921 2,401 Total Major States 131,669 148,818 148,395 146,495 146,717 134,189 126,324 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 1 1 0 2 13 3 3 Total All Major States 131,670 148,819 148,395 146,497 146,730 134,192 126,327 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 3,965 3,489 4,904 2,524 759 1,289 1,623 Assam 2,369 1,702 1,849 1,743 780 959 1,473 Himachal Pradesh 6,536 4,711 4,494 4,119 4,114 998 66,937 Jammu And Kashmir 3,256 3,653 4,158 2,505 5,714 4,570 3,386 Manipur 289 189 230 281 298 71 79 Meghalaya 404 449 517 657 367 464 617 Mizoram 113 163 161 206 130 109 399 Nagaland 350 400 450 480 500 300 350 Sikkim 106 129 194 122 136 160 490 Tripura 298 291 304 270 225 195 244 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 17,686 15,176 17,261 12,907 13,023 9,115 75,598 All States 149,356 163,995 165,656 159,404 159,753 143,307 201,925 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 8,337 3,177 111 1,848 2,588 10,825 14,124 37,256 13,516 8,479 1,437 3,702 13,118 7,687 2,226 128,431 4,577 4 133,012 2001-02 4,620 507 118 2,834 2,453 10,090 11,370 30,645 13,414 8,795 1,512 4,482 9,704 6,831 2,672 110,047 9,893 2200 4 122,144 2002-03 7,110 2,100 73 3,249 2,897 10,152 14,958 49,730 10,458 9,704 1,582 4,163 15,744 8,627 5,652 146,199 10,584 485 9 157,277 2003-04 9,295 2,100 181 4,986 2,548 18,066 18,718 49,675 8,633 4,864 808 3,953 9,021 6,096 4,597 143,541 14,094 282 45 157,962 1,300 1,477 1,654 5,722 97 544 186 250 639 760 3,002 15,631 148,643 2,524 1,525 2,898 7,126 75 782 163 200 665 453 8,070 24,481 146,625 1,561 2,344 3,152 7,269 81 856 380 354 715 409 17,769 34,890 192,167 963 3,676 7,693 5,211 101 1,176 316 343 724 1,470 13,188 34,861 192,823 265 Table 14: Revenue from Major and Medium Irrigation projects in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 7,679 10,380 9,461 6,477 633 510 405 Bihar 1,500 1,700 3,080 3,764 3,572 4,205 5,100 Goa 18 85 47 34 26 23 50 Gujrat 3,099 4,259 3,722 3,753 9,129 13,210 11,068 Haryana 2,038 1,919 2,100 2,430 2,738 6,103 3,830 Karnataka 1,355 1,319 1,693 1,710 1,636 1,845 1,576 Kerala 236 179 266 220 554 671 340 Madhya Pradesh 2,324 4,019 3,649 4,471 2,975 3,735 4,967 Maharashtra 7,829 7,099 7,702 5,800 5,207 3,365 6,163 Orissa 550 492 1,119 654 650 1,117 778 Punjab 1,641 3,145 3,014 2,764 1,069 1,628 1,769 Rajasthan 1,992 2,109 2,144 2,427 2,460 2,340 4,088 Tamil Nadu 367 365 371 464 730 825 985 Uttar Pradesh 16,123 6,548 10,395 10,078 4,086 4,913 4,016 West Bengal 231 304 280 279 242 294 297 Total Major States 46,982 43,922 49,043 45,325 35,707 44,784 45,432 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 21 79 61 60 62 83 523 Total All Major States 47,003 44,001 49,104 45,385 35,769 44,867 45,955 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Assam 17 17 17 11 36 12 16 Himachal Pradesh 0 0 0 0 1 2 3 Jammu And Kashmir 41 41 33 38 41 31 28 Manipur 46 89 31 94 42 19 38 Meghalaya 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 Mizoram 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Nagaland 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Sikkim 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tripura 5 0 4 0 1 0 0 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 109 147 85 143 122 64 85 All States 47,112 44,148 49,189 45,528 35,891 44,931 46,040 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 1,143 3,628 22 13,658 5,430 1,846 382 3,955 6,249 1,871 1,168 3,648 931 28,213 399 72,543 1,038 267 73,848 2001-02 1,027 2,900 1,370 13,209 6,851 2,056 299 2,713 8,603 1,653 1,633 1,843 1,051 11,576 367 57,151 3,820 200 258 61,429 2002-03 847 1,400 426 26,723 5,205 2,093 365 2,464 11,305 2,253 2,447 2,074 952 9,012 349 67,915 5,372 2060 191 75,538 2003-04 1,552 3,000 294 20,278 18,300 1,181 610 3,780 23,069 3,229 1,244 4,323 1,271 13,610 400 96,141 4,485 2060 251 102,937 0 15 2 44 31 0 0 0 0 0 223 315 74,163 0 18 1,106 138 31 0 0 0 0 2 679 1,974 63,403 0 28 6 130 24 0 0 0 0 14 1,038 1,240 76,778 0 26 6 140 34 1 0 0 0 0 936 1,143 104,080 266 Table 15: Revenue from Minor Irrigations in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 1,049 814 740 696 270 255 255 Bihar 315 331 41 92 59 53 562 Goa 16 20 16 13 19 16 15 Gujrat 213 345 381 330 292 268 274 Haryana 6 6 6 307 7 8 8 Karnataka 70 90 122 156 294 239 203 Kerala 48 56 46 100 92 48 55 Madhya Pradesh 898 887 774 711 627 528 1,718 Maharashtra 1,108 1,701 1,459 952 591 1,985 524 Orissa 86 77 192 201 189 244 259 Punjab 16 25 28 23 1,074 11 12 Rajasthan 1,144 1,587 2,321 2,132 1,609 1,847 919 Tamil Nadu 219 258 323 270 236 246 284 Uttar Pradesh 2,191 2,794 4,058 3,675 3,410 3,509 3,661 West Bengal 467 529 506 578 537 651 666 Total Major States 7,846 9,520 11,013 10,236 9,306 9,908 9,415 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 1 4 3 2 1 2 13 Total All Major States 7,847 9,524 11,016 10,238 9,307 9,910 9,428 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 22 45 27 4 2 0 2 Assam 12 21 12 9 10 7 54 Himachal Pradesh 10 11 13 9 11 16 10 Jammu And Kashmir 12 12 12 11 14 47 49 Manipur 2 2 1 0 3 0 5 Meghalaya 2 3 3 4 3 6 5 Mizoram 2 6 2 0 4 1 2 Nagaland 2 3 3 3 3 1 2 Sikkim 0 0 0 1 1 0 2 Tripura 0 0 1 2 1 4 5 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 64 103 74 43 52 82 136 All States 7,911 9,627 11,090 10,281 9,359 9,992 9,564 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 279 60 35 232 10 332 69 762 569 127 41 2,157 287 1,896 623 7,479 152 14 7,645 2001-02 163 403 20 280 11 318 82 1,202 555 170 12 1,916 297 1,773 737 7,939 518 21 10 8,488 2002-03 133 422 1,131 480 7 354 104 1,058 783 198 13 2,673 317 1,211 692 9,576 458 24 10 10,068 2003-04 144 85 181 1,089 12 426 138 722 2,070 378 13 1,823 697 1,853 1,628 11,259 1,016 48 5 12,328 2 14 20 60 7 3 7 2 23 3 9 150 7,795 2 19 46 105 0 7 4 2 8 3 12 208 8,696 1 29 30 110 2 7 1 1 4 10 22 217 10,285 1 20 24 121 1 6 5 1 6 16 65 266 12,594 267 Table 16: Revenue from Power in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 Andhra Pradesh 1,881 2,089 1,734 10 1,985 4,606 Bihar 0 0 9 31 3 497 Goa 9,939 10,938 13,171 15,578 18,161 25,922 Gujrat 18 8 23 12 266 16 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 30 Karnataka 3,910 205 136 9,476 3,278 6,978 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pradesh 14 3 1 0 1 1 Maharashtra 5,191 5,186 147 12,540 7,070 7,551 Orissa 38 18,765 3,257 33 191 187 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tamil Nadu 3 20 2 2 3 4 Uttar Pradesh -5 0 1 0 2 4 West Bengal 2 1 1 1 2 2 Total Major States 20,991 37,215 18,482 37,683 30,962 45,798 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total All Major States 20,991 37,215 18,482 37,683 30,962 45,798 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 569 1,004 785 652 649 1,240 Assam 0 0 0 0 0 0 Himachal Pradesh 657 501 -595 -160 -86 55 Jammu And Kashmir 500 549 420 691 820 10,393 Manipur 896 1,012 925 1,630 872 1,304 Meghalaya 0 0 0 0 0 0 Mizoram 884 909 1,022 1,207 1,138 862 Nagaland 914 965 1,300 1,800 1,980 2,079 Sikkim 358 385 608 586 550 644 Tripura 1,136 914 1,641 1,429 1,504 1,991 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 5,914 6,239 6,106 7,835 7,427 18,568 All States 26,905 43,454 24,588 45,518 38,389 64,366 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 1999-00 2,416 400 29,123 6,803 180 4,692 0 47,887 7,542 272 0 0 5 11 2 99,333 2000-01 4,082 500 33,066 6,446 213 4,333 0 29 8,644 320 0 10 3 9 1 57,656 0 0 99,333 708 0 5,328 21,855 2,222 0 1,328 2,200 833 3,393 37,867 137,200 7 57,663 2001-02 4,733 0 41,840 1 215 3,673 0 5 8,570 318 0 2 6 0 1 59,364 0 0 5 59,369 2002-03 3,551 0 54,835 511 195 2,725 0 24 8,579 294 0 140 6 0 1 70,861 0 0 0 70,861 2003-04 4,490 0 59,215 7,708 221 2,839 0 12 132 290 0 2 25 0 1 74,935 0 0 45 74,980 1,207 0 900 3,387 2,633 0 1,778 2,000 1,004 3,535 0 16,444 74,107 1,186 0 713 4,000 1,973 0 2,304 1,900 1,185 4,620 0 17,881 77,250 1,217 0 -8 5,100 4,391 0 1,821 1,959 1,297 5,968 3,501 25,246 96,107 3,362 1 3,501 7,267 3,677 0 2,614 2,930 1,367 12,178 5,977 42,874 117,854 268 Table 17: Revenue from Petroleum in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Bihar 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Goa 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Gujrat 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Haryana 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pradesh 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Maharashtra 6 22 45 1 1 2 1 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 0 183 252 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttar Pradesh 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total Major States 7 23 46 2 2 186 254 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total All Major States 7 23 46 2 2 186 254 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Assam 25,232 25,756 25,445 24,380 30,196 30,236 31,973 Himachal Pradesh 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Jammu And Kashmir 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Manipur 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Meghalaya 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Mizoram 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 Nagaland 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Sikkim 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Tripura 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 25,232 25,756 25,445 24,380 30,196 30,237 31,973 All States 25,239 25,779 25,491 24,382 30,198 30,423 32,227 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 313 0 0 1 315 0 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 0 315 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 225 1 0 0 227 0 0 0 227 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 204 1 0 1 209 0 0 0 209 0 0 0 3 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 392 2 0 1 400 0 0 0 400 0 36,804 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 36,804 37,119 0 45,458 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 45,458 45,685 0 57,283 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 57,283 57,492 0 72,103 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 72,103 72,503 269 Table 18: Revenue from Village and Small Industries in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 427 493 626 383 949 448 436 Bihar 26 28 37 23 649 36 50 Goa 9 11 15 14 358 14 12 Gujrat 88 51 287 40 163 44 75 Haryana 73 928 126 113 168 113 61 Karnataka 2,159 3,265 2,236 2,541 2,400 2,400 2,240 Kerala 282 135 321 193 149 520 236 Madhya Pradesh 358 382 880 472 422 524 339 Maharashtra 155 177 234 567 920 839 811 Orissa 117 225 104 60 81 76 9 Punjab 161 429 244 565 263 226 143 Rajasthan 118 238 169 120 96 107 17 Tamil Nadu 711 2,076 509 559 466 964 1,337 Uttar Pradesh 184 144 975 97 131 120 777 West Bengal 109 317 246 184 -31 86 99 Total Major States 4,977 8,899 7,009 5,931 7,184 6,517 6,642 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 24 117 112 621 30 314 472 Total All Major States 5,001 9,016 7,121 6,552 7,214 6,831 7,114 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 52 140 61 56 51 56 37 Assam 133 118 197 215 549 77 50 Himachal Pradesh 19 343 63 47 114 31 26 Jammu And Kashmir 47 52 46 34 44 43 64 Manipur 60 23 66 11 14 12 8 Meghalaya 150 18 10 11 15 18 18 Mizoram 9 10 8 10 5 12 5 Nagaland 2 2 2 2 2 2 10 Sikkim 33 33 54 46 41 50 49 Tripura 45 69 47 64 133 39 17 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 550 808 554 496 968 340 284 All States 5,551 9,824 7,675 7,048 8,182 7,171 7,398 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 528 57 22 42 128 2,395 236 331 734 8 132 33 1,654 149 138 6,587 103 763 7,453 2001-02 236 57 14 21 22 2,190 314 269 322 24 98 39 1,267 153 332 5,358 60 11 748 6,177 2002-03 1,453 59 15 526 61 1,725 125 216 119 10 69 12 3,595 278 113 8,376 83 12 563 9,034 2003-04 171 42 101 482 223 1,766 582 278 311 10 93 25 1,829 595 -100 6,408 73 12 312 6,805 43 110 206 67 6 31 8 10 66 50 5 602 8,055 40 364 63 81 10 40 9 11 64 33 12 727 6,904 62 106 97 91 8 35 6 62 63 9 7 546 9,580 50 36 84 87 11 16 16 25 58 12 48 443 7,248 270 Table 19: Revenue from Industries in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 27,574 28,699 36,000 33,032 45,109 27,135 44,091 Bihar 67,500 74,667 76,937 82,072 30 74,155 105,080 Goa 929 917 1,011 943 1,320 1,202 1,260 Gujrat 38,301 41,139 42,882 44,542 46,414 47,296 53,388 Haryana 1,870 2,357 2,328 4,381 5,395 6,676 8,485 Karnataka 5,030 7,995 11,341 10,282 12,733 11,238 12,136 Kerala 506 597 1,135 1,833 1,459 672 1,524 Madhya Pradesh 47,959 60,273 81,270 85,331 82,351 80,983 87,267 Maharashtra 14,256 22,809 28,736 25,940 26,537 25,693 26,918 Orissa 13,122 17,165 24,191 26,946 31,722 31,410 32,017 Punjab 103 181 188 177 367 353 564 Rajasthan 16,414 18,536 21,724 27,205 29,307 30,480 34,979 Tamil Nadu 5,500 6,342 6,753 7,145 9,159 10,111 11,372 Uttar Pradesh 6,365 12,306 14,989 16,029 15,415 15,040 18,123 West Bengal 1,787 1,733 1,819 2,407 1,573 1,411 1,760 Total Major States 247,216 295,716 351,304 368,265 308,891 363,855 438,964 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 11 18 15 15 16 13 17 Total All Major States 247,227 295,734 351,319 368,280 308,907 363,868 438,981 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 0 103 147 526 99 474 1,089 Assam 1,027 676 28 901 884 3,971 305 Himachal Pradesh 1,022 2,828 1,010 3,243 4,018 9,318 7,927 Jammu And Kashmir 75 26 26 96 106 123 181 Manipur 125 130 0 2 76 30 4 Meghalaya 931 2,126 3,654 902 749 2,367 4,991 Mizoram 323 1 405 51 5 170 348 Nagaland 21 3,329 74 1 1 1 5 Sikkim 4 8 11 16 12 17 3 Tripura 149 180 57 112 200 332 409 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 3,677 9,407 5,412 5,850 6,150 16,803 15,262 All States 250,904 305,141 356,731 374,130 315,057 380,671 454,243 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 2000-01 58,451 35,052 1,597 62,141 10,577 14,524 2,111 72,538 35,371 36,045 354 37,075 38,925 19,804 1,763 426,328 20,311 19 446,658 2001-02 61,001 5,054 1,314 73,745 14,003 14,697 1,664 53,281 34,736 37,864 441 41,376 16,065 19,038 1,144 375,423 45,451 82720 12 503,606 2002-03 78,032 6,055 1,579 107,908 11,891 16,123 1,885 59,298 40,071 44,367 760 45,002 18,128 26,268 951 458,318 53,875 81343 17 593,553 2003-04 78,286 7,521 1,942 134,888 7,725 23,193 1,849 64,917 48,253 55,208 1,088 51,457 37,771 25,118 1,781 540,997 63,025 97562 22 701,606 518 61 5,502 318 2 5,711 8 5 5 551 758 13,439 460,097 448 46 5,868 322 1 6,337 1 372 3 627 1,824 15,849 519,455 749 99 4,904 343 1 5,611 0 1 2 604 2,452 14,766 608,319 1,751 37 5,439 402 4 8,618 3 5 4 561 3,213 20,037 721,643 271 Table 20: Revenue from Road Transport in Rs. Lakh Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 Andhra Pradesh 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Bihar 0 0 47 0 906 820 1,955 Goa 0 0 0 0 190 0 0 Gujrat 6 8 16 1 18 2 1 Haryana 25,299 27,197 27,263 30,736 31,960 33,003 33,640 Karnataka 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Kerala 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Madhya Pradesh 0 0 0 0 0 0 50 Maharashtra 0 0 0 0 1 2 0 Orissa 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Punjab 15,654 17,626 17,697 17,534 18,770 21,472 21,095 Rajasthan 0 0 0 0 557 367 0 Tamil Nadu 0 0 0 582 0 0 0 Uttar Pradesh 16 74 91 92 90 99 125 West Bengal 0 0 0 0 8 3 2 Total Major States 40,975 44,905 45,114 48,945 52,500 55,768 56,868 Chattisgarh Jharkhand NCT Delhi 0 0 173 181 0 0 0 Total All Major States 40,975 44,905 45,287 49,126 52,500 55,768 56,868 Special Category States Arunachal Pradesh 410 394 385 470 531 545 607 Assam 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Himachal Pradesh 16 6 8 6 17 9 20 Jammu And Kashmir 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Manipur 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Meghalaya 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 Mizoram 168 146 162 183 212 181 202 Nagaland 400 448 218 461 484 372 430 Sikkim 1,043 819 847 1,379 1,167 749 1,189 Tripura 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Uttaranchal Total Special category States 2,037 1,813 1,620 2,499 2,411 1,859 2,448 All States 43,012 46,718 46,907 51,625 54,911 57,627 59,316 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Note: NA- Value not calculatiable because of Zero or Negative Figure 2000-01 0 50 0 1 37,856 0 0 0 0 0 24,246 0 0 230 3 62,386 0 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 0 62,386 0 1 0 0 41,074 0 0 0 0 0 22,215 0 0 6,180 0 69,470 0 1 0 69,471 0 1 0 0 45,183 0 0 0 1 0 20,001 0 0 15,298 1 80,485 0 1 0 80,486 0 2 0 0 48,221 5 0 0 0 0 41,884 0 0 10,360 0 100,472 0 1 0 100,473 640 0 1 0 0 0 193 483 1,190 0 1 2,508 64,894 722 1 73 0 0 0 171 605 1,556 0 5 3,133 72,604 697 0 0 0 0 0 203 552 1,726 0 3 3,181 83,667 683 1 107 0 0 0 149 575 1,733 0 51 3,299 103,772 272 Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana 1994-95 Table 1: Revenue Expenditure on Social Services (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 295348 343920 467147 521598 547392 705571 733169 803357 821058 858575 1026727 241581 281514 325108 322185 359493 382441 622767 582794 442785 470387 520866 16706 18266 21857 25053 31147 36129 41504 43276 47828 54985 56426 233289 262622 312962 342242 423990 543667 622935 771648 772219 653920 707566 299571 87494 116800 159003 139580 157668 208476 225719 250630 272478 280870 Karnataka 237850 275374 325030 370063 413825 465704 547909 613191 642881 632624 696504 Kerala 177655 208254 231051 269108 308336 334916 420637 418836 407583 503829 502520 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 267507 301852 340615 404033 448177 557428 621038 583646 458289 528426 532165 1599032 463131 530548 656821 746786 867133 942781 1118128 1435071 1413681 1421783 Orissa 96670 148977 183467 201535 221288 272269 400211 311596 325983 345955 370961 Punjab 97730 123154 159091 163922 206216 263954 271632 299271 311060 322164 336770 Rajasthan 219102 252585 302438 346773 374354 492334 548623 612780 640458 658561 714219 Tamil Nadu 358607 384762 433289 512135 561345 710134 764383 779221 767706 797405 859777 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 405308 468124 549908 637420 750142 888230 867702 921796 933659 1030804 1035436 759901 803580 Major 15 states All States 269808 304484 337252 406782 439129 563985 818886 841536 830369 3467786 4021236 4805039 5409215 6109635 7368019 8625243 9268649 9088037 3896061 4490169 5360659 6032756 6831165 8202080 9613797 10450537 10764665 11152844 12002680 9320189 10062120 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Table 2: Revenue Expenditure on Education, Sports, Art and Culture (Rs. in lakh) 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 145939 168952 171525 199348 224293 284066 330825 373881 379420 402574 466577 140136 168264 201326 220686 250700 256280 420508 400688 303340 318100 354693 9120 9907 11941 13821 17810 20103 23680 22609 23761 27760 28062 136920 156097 187117 204990 228964 312463 339295 367236 325815 362397 368340 153587 46025 53603 65130 75368 85518 122099 124907 133062 147615 144719 Karnataka 127812 144813 170295 192980 220125 256096 300090 348261 350141 356401 376603 Kerala 114551 135107 143513 161643 176105 195790 260948 262023 247100 296757 308011 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 124267 136382 165031 189802 198721 257077 302265 274987 211004 229558 235534 943230 269461 304549 366636 421396 487725 531401 727674 940842 938198 893709 Orissa 59440 81524 94255 106610 120839 147969 193037 174158 173334 188279 188183 Punjab 61942 76566 89547 104291 130236 171596 180528 185896 183229 209184 208038 Rajasthan 122867 145228 169779 198304 214709 277320 309199 324281 343098 331054 363489 Tamil Nadu 174092 192034 218059 251687 288957 385303 434872 439600 429287 414533 417506 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 235808 286640 338317 387362 419608 573144 571232 611933 604238 606706 625458 Major 15 states All States 163342 177938 195694 242013 253034 302348 498928 456430 454341 440081 451919 1931722 2237604 2588165 2970301 3317344 4093055 5017988 5315887 5113921 5221812 5489230 2159353 2497736 2891122 3306431 3715995 4564883 5592980 5982585 6017688 6240656 6543822 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 273 Table 3: Revenue Expenditure on Medical and Public Health and Family Welfare (Rs. in lakh) Major States 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana 2002-03 2003-04 51616 56019 60493 76909 84804 103885 109763 128609 131425 134460 147608 45704 50531 65948 50415 54730 58546 101620 99643 71348 74349 70157 3450 3628 4169 4961 5673 7011 7659 8236 8538 9208 10198 35605 41320 46787 51677 62564 84059 91313 89375 71548 84687 87813 9829 14276 16006 18567 22308 29168 28393 29091 31441 34268 35042 Karnataka 39124 45775 49645 52510 62437 70841 86829 90357 98632 95365 95893 Kerala 28422 34324 39658 43222 48906 54522 68804 67388 72934 75950 83170 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 40351 44733 46297 55344 58498 82008 83652 83199 66690 76061 76084 69816 75804 88982 100425 109671 115992 135477 159534 178381 165566 176795 Orissa 11773 21572 25483 27377 29698 40121 42567 43311 42144 45958 45881 Punjab 17085 22617 25685 31484 38323 51609 54456 63759 61817 61034 60845 Rajasthan 38457 46087 51463 59052 62540 81948 85803 87760 97321 89899 101388 Tamil Nadu 54912 61001 69818 77386 89956 109978 114148 116049 118439 118788 120296 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 92283 89813 100519 115506 142187 123394 127020 141022 135611 156502 175385 Major 15 states All States 50688 52624 61750 70815 76348 113271 122750 137662 132279 132907 135479 589115 660124 752703 835650 948643 1126353 1260254 1344995 1318548 1355002 1422034 666938 742853 847877 942987 1071318 1268378 1429807 1540568 1590386 1634138 1717116 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar 17304 Table 4: Revenue Expenditure on Water supply and Sanitation (Rs. in lakh) 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 30819 24837 30690 40095 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 67618 39604 22127 17333 18157 23939 13245 9119 9485 11191 10466 7993 9085 22580 20431 13913 15971 Goa 2227 2623 3354 3626 4471 5630 6507 8429 8743 9733 8003 Gujrat 6874 7872 10241 9645 15998 19338 19369 18661 13548 18511 22253 7612 19341 10728 11463 15084 18252 22209 21941 25755 30369 35348 11856 18054 22108 25525 31675 28326 36133 28913 31975 30291 33477 Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 8322 8833 10204 10311 14505 14964 18234 16315 13187 19527 23030 27639 32480 32306 37789 40797 48016 49714 47824 41591 22946 24707 94361 23777 26433 33025 46613 68853 71308 71272 83008 52438 66757 Orissa 2665 8730 11043 11200 14617 21870 22193 16663 17699 20353 21136 Punjab 3730 6672 9548 9718 10247 12263 11625 15250 18483 22566 25821 Rajasthan 25822 27330 32183 38477 45451 55493 59811 67005 70133 76457 78964 Tamil Nadu 32768 28737 24405 32410 21799 26333 26108 18070 16292 21630 25284 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 19340 22570 25660 29953 52826 39532 31284 30083 48467 26869 40651 Major 15 states All States 9414 14464 12987 14786 21864 27889 32274 40570 40660 25512 28634 208469 264443 273820 322672 406275 465917 468917 455290 430217 425649 498853 242442 297999 314058 366779 457388 527751 540794 546274 557939 556103 653157 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 274 Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Karnataka Table 5: Revenue Expenditure on Housing (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 1994-95 1571 1416 1208 13113 13931 16588 2000-01 7775 2001-02 3686 2002-03 15871 2003-04 16695 28668 46 46 29 30 31 139 119 82 55 69 18 115 120 125 140 159 225 264 277 281 286 276 7046 8799 9789 9142 10735 17266 20337 30634 15873 19789 35713 593 759 702 969 783 629 878 901 971 1064 1000 3765 7163 7426 13619 11080 11809 14078 26339 29531 18650 16984 Kerala 2127 2571 2883 3435 4736 4180 4609 3695 3367 6668 5151 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 3384 3539 3941 3520 4082 6913 6923 6597 6224 6693 7110 13696 13911 17839 15536 18392 24072 21248 30618 19527 39823 33377 Orissa 1178 1954 1911 1924 2150 2186 2458 3095 4657 3697 4099 Punjab 209 214 286 330 290 647 342 0 5 0 0 1843 2128 5518 4900 4827 4077 3626 2596 5663 3774 5654 Rajasthan Tamil Nadu 2437 3469 3837 3091 2752 7440 2267 2639 2845 6173 12129 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 1097 1404 1377 1626 1910 1282 1506 1845 1387 1485 1756 Major 15 states All States 2434 2708 2799 2681 2896 3544 4505 5456 5966 4926 5013 41541 50201 59670 74056 78754 100997 90935 118460 112223 129792 156948 47011 56887 70080 85138 92579 114463 103237 130525 126240 146160 175846 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 1994-95 Table 6: Revenue Expenditure on Urban development (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 6881 6598 5315 6544 7083 14368 3635 10627 34512 42754 57275 3238 3077 2471 3412 3758 3551 3218 4303 5861 8468 11429 400 480 623 548 942 743 832 997 1702 2392 2092 4641 4828 6977 8199 12941 17787 23296 20670 21328 31656 40866 858 1393 2884 3212 3310 4289 5575 6546 4319 5222 5746 2765 4732 11839 9942 9358 6022 9872 8958 9835 8663 28961 921 1206 1354 8381 11735 14759 14672 12159 12259 21929 11733 4233 4632 5224 6846 7039 9188 13116 13911 5758 10099 14059 16040 11954 24634 20898 28192 25554 31111 30699 26800 41437 61649 Orissa 1292 2120 2292 2922 3072 4628 6540 4409 4324 4901 4768 Punjab 990 966 1108 1205 1315 1513 1502 1504 1500 1534 1724 Rajasthan 2155 2772 5135 5187 7541 27803 38460 42165 47454 59686 10571 Tamil Nadu 8349 6025 7052 11066 12960 12409 12961 13164 13294 16550 18258 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 2709 2091 3299 9229 14582 14483 7648 5743 11584 20078 10412 Major 15 states All States 17287 25662 21932 30976 38132 46133 80197 76167 98727 55084 72222 72759 78536 102139 128567 161960 203230 252635 252022 299257 330453 351765 84193 99604 130985 164901 201273 251451 305161 307779 367767 402861 441188 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 275 Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Table 7: Revenue Expenditure on Labour and Labour Welfare (Rs. in lakh) 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 5088 5350 4853 5632 5400 5326 5535 6864 6879 6725 11411 4855 4992 3545 3902 3963 4062 6889 4825 3691 3397 9064 395 414 495 635 729 834 881 968 972 1048 1159 Gujrat 5317 5624 6385 7242 7820 9719 10829 12121 10054 12268 12058 Haryana 2334 2627 3128 3593 3934 5471 5090 5369 5427 5645 5937 Karnataka 2281 2622 2610 2767 3613 4430 6950 6783 7009 6422 6410 Goa Kerala 3745 4575 5238 5441 10576 5809 8776 8850 6296 6815 9137 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 2598 3056 4483 4354 5156 6217 6610 6209 5294 5621 5748 7811 10435 13740 14682 19765 19032 24153 21284 18246 18922 19416 Orissa 953 1529 1385 1888 1668 2403 2246 2242 2136 2182 2218 Punjab 2217 2659 3016 3620 4347 6110 4989 5269 5114 5361 5940 Rajasthan 1599 1893 2449 2514 2471 3666 3415 3508 3639 3732 3982 Tamil Nadu 5586 6489 7027 7008 7563 9188 10479 10773 10492 11462 14505 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 6412 6894 7211 8329 14486 10650 10762 11292 9140 10573 10824 Major 15 states All States 3558 2931 3062 3471 3949 5888 6057 5662 5507 5316 5268 54749 62090 68627 75078 95440 98805 113661 112019 99896 105489 123077 58933 67063 74274 81605 103130 107710 122972 123051 116015 122380 141034 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Table 8: Revenue Expenditure on Social Security and Welfare (Rs. in lakh) 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 10128 10623 10985 14896 18734 21210 18451 30413 31216 45931 51296 18457 23327 23095 17469 10256 19087 28284 24262 16509 21181 34331 613 662 693 798 893 1057 1075 1218 3367 3794 5754 3962 4126 4722 5380 7327 10316 12315 16657 12309 25432 17082 Haryana 11030 18216 15970 18427 18327 19591 26592 38020 39450 39580 41966 Karnataka 16214 17323 20592 22084 22312 27042 28683 31134 34168 34432 43475 Goa Gujrat Kerala 8310 9455 9568 11813 14738 16073 15980 24566 21772 34476 29301 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 9364 10762 12323 19937 26992 36065 39096 34514 29730 43064 41831 65746 17225 18646 21109 22359 23191 27078 29510 47894 42346 53000 Orissa 6302 10423 11892 14387 14634 14834 15025 19156 20830 22562 37494 Punjab 4496 5191 10267 7339 10729 10299 13526 13370 11299 14315 16943 Rajasthan 4085 4301 4613 4746 5000 6607 10883 14424 14727 15301 15603 Tamil Nadu 19431 20548 23553 26627 45484 53897 57913 66481 68960 62660 83641 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 21988 20241 27859 27385 31909 37754 41543 46336 44754 73490 77536 Major 15 states All States 10988 11195 15570 16867 18798 27231 33659 40219 49246 47140 55570 162593 185039 212811 230514 269324 328141 372535 448664 440683 536358 617569 186487 214429 242496 269718 307987 363688 413689 497622 513746 623070 723190 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 276 Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 1994-95 Table 9: Revenue Expenditure on Economic Services (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 251793 289255 227850 494744 421076 411908 384695 633758 694989 640104 735213 218281 181502 176864 156791 155655 217663 307217 229889 177259 218490 202684 14310 16461 18619 20694 25629 32499 41601 49809 54237 53869 61768 263445 259550 300389 349247 417656 534914 548496 812954 777434 649431 552835 87633 161349 119721 169629 177930 215519 179148 154281 241482 253248 270605 180090 206296 244552 320029 289619 333058 400405 438799 539778 480242 465170 80942 93284 110164 135688 194789 229287 230387 217809 190797 298167 299934 257519 213368 261736 374914 305251 346143 403327 329761 436349 342469 627857 588300 437366 467910 496279 660792 628248 544530 525772 765586 587571 763577 Orissa 42875 111720 124713 113283 105570 131622 154769 153247 153483 160278 177138 Punjab 57811 96115 96203 230793 205967 128011 184635 210051 186568 230995 239940 Rajasthan 171888 171806 184135 189384 169662 206483 224261 231250 234915 278456 325738 Tamil Nadu 257239 278856 295696 351578 383507 368131 431581 462801 424238 626162 460740 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 351758 350374 363484 421613 427624 482077 575235 557203 534973 588320 1896970 Major 15 states All States 158964 166736 182313 220194 205410 252409 302594 375463 358642 274201 304444 2831914 3064582 3202718 4209373 4113593 4434254 4894123 5622661 5592715 5858009 7209336 3187761 3373578 3566918 4582640 4547370 4983689 5517675 6400887 6589051 6905232 8460464 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Karnataka 1994-95 Table 10: Revenue Expenditure on Crop Husbandry (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 12463 16622 13799 19933 17719 19426 14298 21676 19792 21063 39899 15210 14649 9542 10691 9193 7958 12906 11371 12514 14176 11680 726 687 737 857 921 969 969 970 1231 1165 1383 12634 11738 12244 13035 13978 15716 20821 23215 49715 21428 27557 5193 4146 4672 5948 5365 7102 7456 7799 8338 8501 8580 17194 12854 14611 16067 17190 20192 22980 23216 21919 24793 32946 Kerala 13629 17454 19107 20373 15609 18404 17373 23779 19633 18904 17259 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 17011 15545 17286 19688 20762 23340 27853 25638 26182 26158 27467 23360 21033 25126 28006 30198 34662 34473 41137 42071 57842 40996 Orissa 4432 8232 9699 13350 13201 16791 16494 15813 14453 15197 32126 Punjab 4242 4529 4799 4756 6518 7267 6471 7028 6601 7648 6525 Rajasthan 9002 10204 12956 13863 12866 15273 12531 13919 14302 13749 15156 Tamil Nadu 78109 91215 63059 70464 84441 94038 144479 75779 61767 53799 40962 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 32893 25463 27587 28084 33743 41709 61690 50137 55063 58313 56527 Major 15 states All States 11842 6919 7629 9018 9916 13681 16397 18198 17810 16417 16033 257940 261290 242853 274133 291620 336528 417191 359675 371391 359153 375096 291247 288797 273612 308507 330562 380834 467520 414520 450718 442937 475294 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 277 Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar 1994-95 Table 11: Revenue Expenditure on Animal Husbandry (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 7060 8319 8349 9151 9940 11257 13514 15848 14805 15417 15773 6508 7007 22892 6480 3449 6560 12653 10328 8554 6798 6907 376 393 407 478 512 629 661 687 743 736 838 Gujrat 3335 4183 4873 5124 5576 6957 8071 8265 6548 7649 7732 Haryana 3463 4185 4669 5907 6166 8667 9108 8906 9028 10077 10506 Karnataka 4881 6130 7224 7427 9432 10254 11321 13113 12030 13445 12892 Goa Kerala 3377 4105 4831 5447 7085 7241 8981 9066 7682 9239 9704 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 7455 8256 9392 10510 10932 15362 15894 17258 13519 14011 14329 7249 8031 9470 10235 12746 13097 15919 19604 20146 17581 17372 Orissa 3241 4581 5022 5354 5972 7589 7926 7510 7341 7687 8088 Punjab 2694 4072 4845 5083 6939 8271 7798 9708 9540 9458 9716 Rajasthan 5574 5479 6074 6744 7860 10056 10255 10466 10184 10169 11339 Tamil Nadu 6972 7471 8248 9038 9519 12285 12436 11336 11482 10996 10506 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 9891 9549 11053 11271 16222 14231 12396 12551 12153 15099 17877 Major 15 states All States 4808 4876 5454 6610 7016 10973 12461 13929 12357 12245 11989 76884 86637 112803 104859 119366 143429 159394 168575 156112 160607 165568 93742 103440 132101 125921 143302 171069 192294 204770 202113 207901 217634 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Karnataka 1994-95 Table 12: Revenue Expenditure on Fisheries (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 1256 1060 1162 1231 1803 1472 1457 1806 1904 1755 1867 1100 819 867 768 921 282 945 1823 1655 1204 1155 200 200 190 228 226 265 401 294 284 237 260 1154 1315 1490 1673 2093 2614 2614 2715 1590 1793 3765 381 355 547 533 504 776 740 847 686 845 935 1455 1540 1902 1880 2196 1970 1989 2577 2259 1875 1909 Kerala 2491 2677 3418 3152 5840 5583 6162 4694 3717 5224 3795 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 1212 1187 1305 1824 1633 1796 2082 1615 1231 1324 1336 1280 1431 1555 1748 1874 1971 2652 2369 1693 1766 2210 Orissa 603 1232 1419 1504 1404 1838 1713 2202 1714 2071 2406 Punjab 119 282 263 295 376 508 440 501 527 547 540 Rajasthan 479 525 546 503 486 636 588 591 672 681 660 Tamil Nadu 1722 2723 2295 3584 2419 3572 2943 2775 3323 3245 4265 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 1785 1402 1479 1444 1447 1195 2267 2051 2416 2246 2438 Major 15 states All States 1944 2289 2695 3612 2239 5014 6501 6997 5360 3468 2821 16900 19085 21034 24132 24822 30155 34372 33689 28580 28232 30307 20962 22586 25000 28580 29993 35192 41090 40680 37636 37075 39631 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 278 Table 13: Revenue Expenditure on Forestry and Wild Life (Rs. in lakh) 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 7219 7766 9948 13080 16468 18332 19381 25582 20708 20052 31694 6407 6450 5282 6959 6234 8038 16795 10986 3919 4466 4880 380 425 438 523 567 673 874 1029 872 900 1098 5240 6161 7195 7533 8933 11145 11522 12037 12206 12323 14024 4671 4691 5306 5104 5297 6767 6039 5634 6563 7251 7277 13780 15068 17066 16711 20529 27792 30070 29065 30249 24968 33566 4802 6745 7174 8704 7957 10425 12610 13348 13349 14088 14829 32064 34357 39119 48327 49303 60964 62999 49550 45562 48543 54450 19212 22469 23928 28268 29286 31497 41339 32321 28413 28919 33548 Orissa 2242 5442 5779 5649 5390 6666 7984 9120 8853 9055 8286 Punjab 698 1840 1873 1873 2134 4235 6040 10442 10029 8334 9705 8155 11095 6836 7451 8255 10440 11685 12481 13015 13004 14026 Rajasthan Tamil Nadu 4158 4511 5056 5429 6146 8126 8529 9202 8532 8666 9121 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 9831 9096 10790 12871 16468 18029 19293 18616 16453 11812 11832 Major 15 states All States 7166 7909 8763 10153 9746 11115 15872 16291 16273 13011 12626 126025 144025 154553 178635 192713 234244 271032 255704 234996 225392 260962 157435 172177 187485 213689 230955 286032 329295 328343 364133 368806 386400 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Table 14: Revenue Expenditure on Co-operation (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 1994-95 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 8285 5389 5977 4960 4095 7949 7343 5628 7127 15007 5858 4577 4655 4397 4829 3972 4219 7810 6609 4016 3599 3298 95 98 117 150 166 209 216 213 224 224 227 15769 4343 3146 4046 3216 4603 5417 4577 3541 4274 4517 Haryana 1101 1511 1646 1749 1457 1845 1829 1882 1901 1939 2137 Karnataka 2732 4162 13882 5034 3698 4061 5109 4205 4121 3986 9010 Goa Gujrat Kerala 2541 2996 2999 3138 3164 3429 4281 4480 3414 6876 4364 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 4184 4308 5234 3725 7165 5814 3977 4127 3046 3561 3310 7386 7301 8542 17572 12104 16209 17496 18482 14457 13900 24927 Orissa 1874 1959 5212 2297 2232 3121 3177 3244 3075 3202 3168 Punjab 1497 2128 7935 2492 3260 3857 3473 3862 3730 4066 4183 Rajasthan 5647 4763 3747 2748 2304 2660 2291 2108 2419 2191 2396 Tamil Nadu 7310 5038 6755 6271 7172 8565 9584 10461 16023 15761 21863 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 5535 3023 3679 4031 4786 5151 4761 4826 4543 4889 5526 Major 15 states All States 1517 1590 1890 2227 2526 4157 4289 3851 3867 3669 3392 70050 53264 75158 65269 61317 75849 81053 78555 75504 87144 98176 75386 58751 83472 73898 69271 83546 89810 88018 88323 99821 113591 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 279 Table 15: Revenue Expenditure on Major and Medium Irrigation (Rs. in lakh) 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar 0 Goa Gujrat 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 0 71182 82010 94439 104891 105318 129539 134213 157446 172656 0 0 8349 10676 3244 9089 21918 21179 19303 18624 17274 0 0 332 445 485 583 637 763 599 658 671 0 0 73174 83467 98151 131096 152620 172900 169414 180751 21445 Haryana 0 0 22733 22638 25332 26081 27791 27965 34477 37189 38074 Karnataka 0 0 34388 41969 47648 48895 59365 65061 6859 6901 6319 Kerala 0 0 3470 3502 3878 4230 4623 5392 4415 6802 8127 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 0 0 17115 17961 20405 26178 27618 27121 21647 21103 22395 0 0 106193 124209 140675 149141 159089 160114 163557 165442 15066 Orissa 0 0 4524 5102 5366 5838 6704 7012 7348 7433 7569 Punjab 0 0 13542 15432 16766 18586 19026 22066 22212 24822 39946 Rajasthan 0 0 33557 37141 40586 52964 55664 58667 62237 61600 68700 Tamil Nadu 0 0 14898 19013 24010 29163 30649 34769 34594 40327 44976 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 0 0 61161 61738 71829 70373 94353 105473 98068 107290 111743 0 0 8562 9979 11133 14077 17189 19087 16139 15182 14218 Major 15 states All States 0 0 473180 535282 603947 691185 782564 857108 795082 851570 589179 0 0 474182 537757 606968 694607 786977 867100 818458 880362 617259 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 1994-95 Andhra Pradesh Bihar 0 Goa Gujrat Table 16: Revenue Expenditure on Minor Irrigation (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 0 6071 4112 7772 5807 7401 11999 16687 11118 7155 0 0 10221 12273 14021 9960 15882 16080 12904 12527 13030 0 0 273 400 396 574 663 962 693 689 614 0 0 12353 10561 13428 17026 21283 19589 10195 12241 14742 Haryana 0 0 894 617 994 449 827 767 2003 5484 818 Karnataka 0 0 4548 5531 6372 6425 7641 8484 8597 8267 8891 Kerala 0 0 5154 4462 3967 6265 5981 5633 4871 5558 6779 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 0 0 4127 4268 4878 3870 3947 4275 3602 3485 4147 0 0 23768 24367 24218 25209 16306 23995 22599 14603 19457 Orissa 0 0 6179 10321 6429 7920 7061 7602 7911 8273 7533 Punjab 0 0 2260 2443 2177 2827 3841 5003 5626 4614 4414 Rajasthan 0 0 5338 5517 5573 6758 6562 7858 6816 5987 5895 Tamil Nadu 0 0 4605 4181 5095 6753 5672 5043 2908 3427 3802 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 0 0 60972 72331 56791 62172 12916 18530 27620 28118 24505 0 0 11224 13016 15970 20748 25855 33195 28797 23238 24101 Major 15 states All States 0 0 157987 174400 168081 182763 141838 169015 161829 147629 145883 0 0 165924 188519 184793 202724 163853 196950 195928 192519 191465 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 280 Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Table 17: Revenue Expenditure on Power (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 1994-95 3232 3765 3381 225221 95803 5662 2000-01 16511 2001-02 79859 2002-03 230470 2003-04 164349 164166 51513 42578 44 0 15627 1624 0 0 0 9989 0 9420 10620 12062 13392 17756 22583 30133 37263 40520 36994 42126 256081 81142 70828 68675 10458 136660 164517 138489 354676 355025 221863 Haryana 6000 45500 21000 63245 67994 84715 41310 14023 79041 84949 97957 Karnataka 4486 15054 30693 96056 60219 67334 77582 92020 232115 190095 172224 Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 0 20 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 23193 57247 68760 22332 32550 122371 39053 43489 117079 41033 203701 97977 395434 34790 1599 977 1398 90458 1791 1702 2946 239560 71564 75438 Orissa 7271 25169 27143 948 665 1252 344 494 1566 4646 2688 Punjab 0 0 0 133809 87347 0 40368 60458 45000 75200 135122 38572 17815 23217 44773 27530 29780 48085 47826 31810 66200 94314 0 0 0 0 0 0 51 71 3325 200116 43818 8479 0 3430 0 0 0 0 0 35000 41372 1342672 Rajasthan Tamil Nadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal Major 15 states All States 4602 5000 8171 15617 9069 5143 5122 14779 10085 32 30 285076 259658 231764 816348 559514 427801 518020 982062 1339222 1292413 2838669 311976 292523 269305 859372 609290 554777 675319 1190746 1522394 1404871 3007904 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Karnataka Table 18: Revenue Expenditure on Village and Small Industries (Rs. in lakh) 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 7399 6169 5889 8256 9298 12239 4475 7631 11118 13005 13396 2007 1313 2945 7536 4256 2513 4539 4679 2421 2509 2778 530 522 735 494 409 346 481 647 1009 1264 948 7350 11541 13350 10404 10653 19010 15144 16753 12291 12559 8986 1111 1214 2331 1733 927 776 491 556 379 878 492 11200 15055 17372 17812 16431 17030 20113 22441 27089 26251 20541 Kerala 5141 6205 9937 12364 9508 8529 9296 7721 10806 9858 9364 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 4508 4659 5887 5962 4576 5948 5865 5965 3828 4691 5237 2619 2725 2674 2828 2809 3151 3010 2795 2373 2835 2656 Orissa 1428 4908 4624 4576 4287 4934 4648 3297 3201 3067 3821 Punjab 1030 1560 1730 1854 2118 2617 2264 2250 2186 2159 2041 Rajasthan 1116 1023 1137 2016 1404 1576 1255 1235 1112 1215 1803 Tamil Nadu 18087 17805 21094 23338 15128 23250 15937 19663 15325 25030 18827 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 7005 4285 8726 8175 6056 7015 7807 9620 6986 8326 9174 Major 15 states All States 4948 6071 6766 6878 6540 7431 8702 11180 7618 6497 7098 75479 85055 105197 114226 94400 116365 104027 116433 107742 120144 107162 93229 100843 123087 135109 117467 141012 130953 147854 143569 161076 149551 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 281 Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Haryana Karnataka 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 3439 4721 6861 5915 6863 4307 7609 3176 5010 5928 7395 2983 2938 2156 2999 5241 3035 5216 4411 2115 2504 2498 40 44 53 68 67 79 80 89 153 190 643 1351 2153 2574 2388 2754 4373 9298 11802 24227 14108 9284 Goa Gujrat Table 19: Revenue Expenditure on Industries (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 1994-95 740 827 878 924 1088 3057 1999 1976 2047 2826 1995 7872 6811 5840 6713 5793 5452 10584 10491 6818 5023 2515 Kerala 2115 2445 609 2337 1377 1837 1714 1263 534 1963 9661 Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 2340 2323 4286 2850 7949 2976 2086 2856 1585 1928 1417 1864 9020 11814 17595 7822 6941 6217 1113 10927 15719 17417 Orissa 393 1133 1081 1089 1291 1739 1714 1366 1252 1494 1382 Punjab 54 2542 1723 577 3087 1185 1553 605 101 102 94 6575 9363 12377 11352 10605 9668 6239 4538 4135 5283 5896 Rajasthan Tamil Nadu 1268 3609 2451 2076 2404 2731 1045 3157 1011 3208 1891 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 1257 1338 1549 1795 2070 2349 2414 11569 5486 3650 12365 Major 15 states All States 2595 4074 3799 3722 3968 4388 4405 5786 10126 4223 9662 34886 53341 58051 62400 62379 54117 62173 64198 75527 68149 84115 45608 60197 64881 71680 72063 65954 75873 80422 96149 90834 106228 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. Major States 1993-94 Andhra Pradesh Bihar Goa Gujrat Haryana Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra 1994-95 Table 20: Revenue Expenditure on Roads and Bridges (Rs. in lakh) 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 15765 16235 17018 26358 32008 11060 11485 12752 14877 718 829 1033 810 23504 28101 29934 34807 4833 5611 7010 13237 14087 3484 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 35891 47783 43153 47449 48380 45226 10402 8526 27908 25862 21567 22457 22897 1072 1844 2124 2286 2184 2838 3407 45120 54237 54086 55174 43353 51364 58381 7336 7582 14289 13589 11797 14217 8992 12456 16337 18440 21821 30612 35099 36399 32639 27742 9103 9172 14019 15199 16977 19834 24537 24615 23310 44805 43448 26584 31218 34719 37464 39910 42036 30944 29331 24507 22400 17076 48191 60147 66441 77136 92264 11622 1561 4070 7189 94025 25500 Orissa 8253 10021 11286 11830 10588 10121 13817 14212 12393 14034 12587 Punjab 8070 8050 9083 9091 11379 13198 13794 11117 10714 14592 6647 14203 14309 16395 15682 14411 18085 15385 17993 19148 25645 20849 Rajasthan Tamil Nadu 23550 24932 29776 34320 37996 33532 32368 26255 26312 36620 44924 Uttar Pradesh West Bengal 29721 27042 26568 29417 30807 31677 43474 52745 53652 67473 67659 Major 15 states All States 9464 11468 14383 13162 12035 15765 27072 34979 25987 19193 31650 246256 272707 293901 343826 380991 332478 379054 388688 368381 505457 440449 277394 313897 350618 391377 431168 391050 446207 471591 476924 620650 564437 Source: RBI, "State Finances: A Study of Budgets", Various Issues, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai. 282 References Ainsworth, M 1984. “User Charges for Cost Recovery in Social Sectors: Current Practices.” Country Policy Department Discussion Paper, World Bank, Washington. Alberta H. Charney, Gary C. Woodard. 1984. “A Test of Consumer Demand Response to Water Prices: Comment”. Land and Economics, 60 (4) Nov.: 414-416. Amacher, Gregory S, Richard J Brazee and Meindert Witvliet. 2001. “Royalty Systems, Government Revenues, and Forest Conditions: An Application from Malaysia” Land Economics 77: 300-313. Anand, Mukesh and Raghabendra Jha. 2004. “Budgetary Subsidies and Fiscal Deficit: Case of Maharashtra”. Economic and Political Weekly 39 (August 21): 3827-3834. Aruna R., 1999. “Learn Thoroughly: Primary Schooling in Tamil Nadu” Economic and Political Weekly, May 1: 1011-1014. Augenblick, M., and Scott, C.B.Jr. 1990. The Build, Operate and Transfer (BOT) Approach to infrastructure Projects in Developing Countries” World Bank Policy Research and External Affairs Division Working Paper No. 448, Washington, D.C. Bahl, R.W. and J.F. Linn. 1992. Urban Public Finance in Developing Countries. A World Bank Book. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bailey, Stephen J. 1994. “User Charges for Urban Services.” Urban Studies 31(4/5): 745-765. Balestrino, Alessandro. 1999. “User Charges as Redistributive Devices”. Journal of Public Economic Theory: 511-524. Banerjee, Abhijit, Angus Deaton and Esther Duflo. 2004. “Health Care Delivery in Rural Rajasthan”. Economic and Political Weekly 39 (February 28): 944-949. Barah, Bhuban C. 1996. Fiscal instruments for Environmental Sustainability: Reforms for Urban water utility services and environmental pollution. National Institute for Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi. Barro, R., and X. Sala-i-Martin. 2004. Economic Growth. 2nd edition, New Delhi: Prentice Hall of India Basu, Rama V. 2003. “Privatisation of Health Services: A South Asian Perspective”, Economic and Political Weekly 38: (October 18): 4433-4437. Besley, Timothy. 1991. “Welfare Improving User Charges for Publicly Provided Private Goods”. Journal of Economics 93: 495-510. Bierhanzl, Edward J. 1999. “Incentives for Efficiency: User Charges and Municipal Spending”. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice/Economia Delle Scelte Pubbliche 17: 19-34. ___. and Paul B. Downing. 1998. “User Charges and Bureaucratic Inefficiency”. Atlantic Economic Journal 26:175-189. Bird, R.M. 1976. Charging for Public Services: A New Look at an Old Idea. Canadian Tax Foundation, Toronto. 283 ___. 1997. “Analysis of Earmarked Taxes”. Tax Notes International (June 23): 20952116. ___. 2001. “User Charges in Local Government Finance”. In The Challenge of Urban Government: Policies and Practices, ed. Mila Freire and Richard Stern, World Bank Institute of Development Studies, Washington, D.C. ___, and Thomas Tsiopoulos. “User Charging in the Federal Government- A Background Document.” Downloaded from Internet. Bloom, D., D. Canning, and J. Sevilla, 2004. “The Effect of Health on Economic Growth: A Production Function Approach.” World Development Report 2004; 32:1-13, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Boiteux, M. 1960. “Peak Load Pricing”. Journal of Business, 33, (2), April: 157-79. ___. 1971: “On the Management of Public Monopolies Subject to Budget Constraints”. Journal of Economic Theory, 3: 219-40. Braeutigam, R.R. 1980. “An Analysis of Fully Distributed Cost Pricing in Regulated Industries”. Bell Journal of Economics, 11 (1) Spring: 182-196. Bridger M. Mitchell. 1978. “Optimal Pricing of Local Telephone Service”. American Economic Review, 68 (4), September: 517-537. Brito, D.L. and W.H. Oakland. 1980. “On the Monopolistic Provision of Excludable Public Goods”. The American Economic Review, 11 (1) September: 691-706. Brown, S.J. and D.S. 1996. The Theory of Public Utility Pricing. New York: Cambridge University Press. Burns, M.E. and C Walsh. 1981. “Market Provision of Price-Excludable Public Goods: A General Analysis”. Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 89 (11):166-191. Calthrop, E. and S. Proost. 1998. “Road Transport Externalities: Interaction between Theory and Empirical Research”. Environmental and Resource Economics 11: 335-348. Canton, E. 2002. Higher Education Reform: Getting the Incentives Right. CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis, The Hague. Chamarbagwala Rubiana. 2004. “Returns to Education, Child Labor and Schooling in India.” Working Paper. Department of Economics, Indiana University, Bloomington. Chia, Ngee-Choon. 1998. “Singapore: The Significance of Motor Vehicle Taxes in the Revenue System.” Asia-Pacific Tax Bulletin (July): 275-28. Clark, J.M. 1911. “Rates for Public Utilities.” American Economic Review, I, September: 473-87. Coase, R.H. 1946. "The Marginal Cost Controversy". Economica, New Series. 13(51), Aug.: 1-44. ___. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law & Economics, 3(1): 1-44. Coelli, Tim, Antonio Estache, Sergio Perelman, and Lourdes Trujillo. 2003. A Primer on Efficiency Measurement for Utilities and Transport Regulator, WBI Development Studies, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Cremer, Helmuth, and Jean-Jacques Laffont. 2003. “Public Goods with Costly Access.” Journal of Public Economics 87: 1985-2012. Elsevier. 284 Dalton, Huge. 1949. Principles of Public Finance. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul Ltd.: 32. Daramola, A G, Hawa A Biu, Ogoh Alubo, Agi S P I Shebu, Uchenne m Nzewi, and Paul Francis. 1998. Hard Lessons: Primary Schools, community, and Social Capital in Nigeria. World Bank, Washigton, DC. Das, Jishnu and Jeffrey Hammer. 2004. “Strained Mercy: Quality of Medical Care in Delhi”. Economic and Political Weekly 39(February 28): 951-961. Devarajan, Shantayanan and Shekhar Shah. 2004. “Making Services Work for India's Poor”. Economic and Political Weekly 39 (February 28): 907-919. Dobbs, Ian M. 1991. “Litter and Waste Management: Disposal Taxes versus User Charges.” Canadian Journal of Economics 24(1): 221-227. Downing, P.B. 1992. “The Revenue Potential of User Charges in Municipal Finance.” Public Finance Quarterly 20: 512-527. Dreze J. and A. Sen. 1995. “India: Economic Development and Social Opportunity” Oxford University press. Dupuit, J. 1844. “On the Measurement of the Utility in Public Works.” Annales des Ponts et Chausses, Series No. 2, No. 8 (English Translation by R.H. Barback in International Economic Papers, No. 2, 1952). Edling, Herbert. “Non-Tax Revenue of Sub-national Governments: Theoretical Background, Experience from the International Perspective and Recommendations.” Fiscal Policy Series 105, Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. EPW Research Foundation, 1994. “Social Indicators of Development for India – II: Interstate Disparities” Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.XXIX, No 21, May 21, (Special Statistics – 8). Ferroni, Marco, and Ashoka Mody, ed. 2002. International Public Goods: Incentives, Measurement and Financing. World Bank, Kluwer Academic Publishers. Fraser, C.D. 1996. “On the Provision of Excludable Public Goods.” Journal of Public Economics 60: 111-130. Fraser, Rob, and Ross KingwelI. 1997. “Can Expected Tax Revenue be Increased by an Investment Preserving Switch from ad-valorem Royalties to a Resource Rent Tax?” Resources Policy 23: 103-108. Fraser, Rob. 1999. “An Analysis of the Western Australian Gold Royalty.” Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 43: 35-50. Friedlender, A.F. 1969. The Dilemma of Freight Transport Regulation. The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC. Gertler, Paul J., and Jeffrey S. Hammer. 1997. “Strategies for Pricing Publicly Provided Health Services.” A Working Paper, Public Economics Division, Policy Research Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. Global Forum for Health Research. 2004. “Strengthening Health Systems: The Role and Promise of Policy and Systems Research.” Alliance for Health Policy and Systems Research, World Health Organisation, Geneva. Goel, Nihal Chand 2000. Resource Mobilization Strategy for Indian States; Jaipur: Pointex Publishers. 285 Gokhale, Yogesh, “Reviving Traditional Forest Management”. Economic and Political Weekly. 39 (July 31): 3556-3559. Government of India. 1988. Rates for Surface Water in India. Central Water Commission, New Delhi. ___. 1992. “Pricing of Irrigation Water.” Report of the Committee, Planning Commission, New Delhi. ___. 2000. “Notification of Rates of Royalty and Dead Rent.” Ministry of Mines, New Delhi. ___. 2001. “Minor Irrigation for formulation of the Tenth Plan (2002-2007) Proposals.” Minor Irrigation Division, Ministry of Water Resources, New Delhi. ___. 2005. Financing and Delivery of Health Care Services in India. Background Papers of the National Commission on Macroeconomics and Health (August). Ministry of Health and Family Welfare, New Delhi. ___. 2006. “Report of the National Forest Commission.” New Delhi: Ministry of Environment and Forest. ___. 2006. The Secretariat for the Committee on Infrastructure. Financing of the National Highway Development Programme. Report of the Core Group, Planning Commission, New Delhi. Government of Karnataka. 2000. Karnataka Minerals Policy. Bangalore. ___. 2001. Final Report of the Tax Reform Commission. Finance Department, Bangalore. ___. 2002. Division: Shaping Education in Karnataka. Bangalore. ___. 2002. Major and Minor Bridges in Karnataka, as on 31st March, 2000. Public Works Department, Bangalore. ___. 2003. Karnataka Revenue Reforms Commission, First Report, Volumes 1 and 2. ___. 2003. Report of the Task Force on Higher Education. (Restructuring of Grantsin-Aid Policy by the Government of Karnataka), Bangalore. Government of Rajasthan. 1999. “Issues and constraints”. In Sector Strategy for Water Supply and Sanitation. Jaipur Water Supply and Sanitation Feasibility Studies, Jaipur. ___. 2005. “Mineral Policy, 2005.” Department of Mines, Jaipur. ___. 2006. “An Outline of Major and Minor Minerals.” Department of Mines and Geology, Jaipur. Government of Uttaranchal 2004-05. Uttaranchal at a Glance; Department of Planning, Dehradun. Gronau, Reuben. 1994. “Fuel Taxes and Road User Charges in LDCs: Some Lessons from Sub Saharan Africa”. In The Environment and Transport, Environmental Analysis and Economic Policy, ed. Yoshitsugu Hayashi, Kenneth Button and Peter Nijkamp. Vol. 4 Cheltenham: U.K. and Northampton, Mass.: Edward Elgar. Gupta, I., and A. Mitra. 2003. “Economic Growth, Health, and Poverty: An Exploratory Study in India.” In Mishra R., R. Chatterjee, S. Rao (eds). India Health Report, New Delhi: Oxford University Press. 286 Gupta, I., and P. Dasgupta. 2000. “Demand for Cuartive Health Care in Rural India: Choosing Between Private, Public and No Care.” A Discussion Paper, Institute of Economic Growth, New Delhi. Gwilliam, Kenneth M., and Zmarak M. Shalizi. 1996. “Road funds, User Charges and Taxes.” TWU Paper, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Heggie, Ian G., and Piers Vickers. 1998. “Commercial Management and Financing of Roads.” World Bank Technical Paper No. 409, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Hope, R.A 2006. “Evaluating Water Policy Scenarios Against the Priorities of the Rural Poor.” World Development 34(1): 167-179. U.K.: Elsevier. Hotelling, H. 1938. “The General Welfare in Relation to Problems of Taxation and of Railway and Utility Rates.” Econometrica, Vol. 6(3): 139-167. Hotelling, H. 1939. “The Relation of Prices to Marginal Cost in an Optimum System”. Econometrica, 7: 151-155. Hsiao, W., and Y. Liu. 1996. “Economic Reforms and Health: Lessons from China.” New England Journal of Medicine; 335: 430-432. Huber, Bernd and Marco Runkel. 2004. “Tax Competition, Excludable Public Goods and User Charges”. CesIfo Working Paper No. 1172. Hyde, William F and Roger A Sedjo. 1992. “Managing Tropical Forests: Reflections on the Rent Distribution Discussion”. Land Economics 68: 343-350. Jha, Raghbendra, M.N.Murty, and Satya Paul. 1990. Pricing of Postal Services in India. New Delhi: National Institute of Public Finance and Policy. Jimmenmez, E. 1987. Pricing Policy in the Social Sectors-Cost Recovery for Education and Health in Developing Countries, World Bank, Baltimore: The John Hopkins University Press. Joshi, A., and P.N. Pande. 1991. “Forest Policy and its Impact on the Rural Population in Uttar Pradesh Hills.” A Working Paper, Giri Institute of Development Studies, Lucknow. Kafoglis, M. 1963. “Highway policy and External Economies.” National Tax Journal, Vol. 16: 68-80. ___. 1977. “The potential of local service charges.” in Local Service Pricing Policies and Their Effect on Urban Spatial Structure, edited by Paul B Downing. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press. Kahn, A. 1970. The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions, Vol. 1, New York: Wiley and Sons Kattan, Raja Bentaouet, and Nicholas Burnett. 2004. “User Fees in Primary Education.” Working Paper, World Bank. Keefer, Philip and Stuti Khemani. 2004. “Why Do the Poor Receive Poor Services”? Economic and Political Weekly 39 (February 28): 935-943. Kneese, A.V. and C.L. Schultze. 1975. Pollution, Prices, and Public Policy. Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C. Krishnamurthy, M.S. 1999. “Review of Resources from Non Tax Revenue.” Finance Department, Government of Karnataka, Bangalore. 287 Kumar R., Santra S., Mukherjee A., Banerjee T., and Kundu M., 2005. Public-Private Interface in Primary Education: A Case Study in West Bengal, Economic and Political Weekly, April 9: 1550-1555. Levesque, Jean-Frederic, Slim Haddad, Delampady Narayana, and Pierre Fournier. 2006. “Outpatient Care Utilisation in Urban Kerala, India.” The London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, London: Oxford University Press. Listorti, James A. 1990. “Environmental Health components for Water Supply, Sanitation, and Urban Projects.” Working Paper No. 121, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Mahal, Ajay, Abdo S. Yazbeck, David H. Peters, and G.N.V. Ramana. 2001. The Poor Health and Service Use in India (March). Mathur, Archana S., and Arvinder S. Sachdeva. 2003. “Towards an Economic Approach to Sustainable Forest Development.” Planning Commission Working Paper 2/2003-PC, Government of India, New Delhi. Mathur, O P. 2001. “Coming to the Grips with Issues of Pricing Urban Water and Intra-City Bus Transport.” National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi. Mehrotra, S. et al, 1998. “Reallocating Public Spending for Basic Social Services in Developing Countries.” Economic and Political Weekly, July 4:1717-1724. Mehrotra, Santosh. 2004. “Reforming Public Spending on Education and Mobilising Resources: Lessons from International Experience”. Economic and Political Weekly 39 (February 28): 987-997. Mills, A., R. Brugha, K. Hanson, and B. McPake. 2002. “Approaches for Improving Delivery in the Non-state Sector: What Is the Evidence on what works, where and why?” Paper presented at the Making service Works for the Poor Conference. Eynsham Hall, Oxfordshire. November 4. Mohan P., S. Iyengar, S.B. Mohan, K. Sen. 2003. “Daily Up-Down”. Why should an auxiliary nurse-mid-wife (ANM) of Rajasthan prefer to reside within her work-area? Action Research and Training for Health, Udaipur. Mookherjee, Dilip and Ivan P.L. Png. 1994. “Marginal Deterrence in Enforcement of Law”. Journal of Political Economy 102: 1039-1066. Musgrave, Richard A. and Peggy B Musgrave. 1989. Public Finance in Theory and Practice, 5th edition, Boston: McGraw Hill Book Company. Narayan, Deepa, and Patti Pettesch. 2002. From Many Lands: Voices of Poor. World Bank, Washington, DC: Oxford University Press. Narayana, M.R. 2001. Sub-sector Study on Collegiate Education. Education Department, Government of Karnataka, Bangalore. Nellor, David C.L. and Emil M. Sunley. 1994. “Fiscal Regimes for Natural Resource Producing Developing Countries” International Monetary Fund Papers on Policy Analysis and Assessment, No. 9424. Newbery, David M., and Georgina Santos. 1999. “Road Taxes, Road User Charges and Earmarking.” The Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, Vol. 20, No. 2:103-132. Nordin, J.A. 1976. “A Propsosed Modification on Taylor’s Demand–Supply Analysis: Comment”. The Bell Journal of Economics, 7(2):719-721. 288 Oakland, W.H. 1987. “Theory of Public goods.” In Handbook of Public Economics ed. Auerbach, A.J. and M. Feldstein, Vol. II, Amsterdam, North Holland: 485-536. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (O.E.C.D.). 1987. “Toll Financing and Private Sector Involvement in Road Infrastructure.” O.E.C.D., Paris. Osmundsen, Petter. 1998. “Dynamic Taxation of Non Renewable Natural Resources under Asymmetric Information about Reserves.” Canadian Journal of Economics 31: 933-951. Pandey, R. 1997. “Water Demand Management: Issues in Pricing and Cost Recovery.” National Institute for Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi. Patankar, P.G., 1994. “Policy Reforms for Road Development.” Paper presented at the Seminar on Privatisation of Roads: Need and Issues, Organised by the Indian Merchants’ Chamber, Mumbai. Paul, S., S. Balakrishna, K. Gopakumar, S. Sekhar, and M. Vivekananda. 2004. “State of India’s Public Services: Benchmarks for the States”. Economic and Political Weekly, February 28: 90-134. PROBE Team in association with Centre for Development Economics. 1999. Public Report on Basic Education in India. New Delhi: Oxford University Press. Purohit Brijesh C. 1996. “New Directions for Public Health Financing” Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. XXXI, No. 8, Feb. 24: 450-453. ___. 1997. “Structural Adjustment and Health Care Sector in India: Some Policy Issues in Financing”, QEH Working Paper No.2 (on Internet), University of Oxford, April. ___. 2001. “Structural Adjustment, Private Initiatives and Policy Options: A Case of the Indian Healthcare Sector” Health Policy and Planning, 16(1), January-March, 87-97, Oxford University Press, U.K. ___. 2004. Inter-State Disparities in Health Care and Financial Burden on the Poor in India, Journal of Health and Social Policy, Vol. 18(3), 2004: 37-60, Howarth Press, USA. ___. and Siddiqui, T. 2004. “Environmental Determinants of Disease and Mortality Pattern in India: A Factor Analytic Approach.” In Chugan P.K and Mallikarjun M. (Eds.), Managing Trade, Technology and Environment, New Delhi: Excel Books. Purohit, Mahesh C. 1999 “Road User Taxation in India- A Comparative Perspective.” International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation Amsterdam (May). Rakshit, Mihir. 2006, “Issues in Infrastructural Investment: National Highway Development Programme.” Money and Finance, Vol. 2, ICRA, New Delhi. Ram, Rati. 1982. “Public Subsidization of Schooling and inequality of Educational Access.” Comparative Education Review. 26 (1) (February):36-47. Ramsey, F.P.1927. “A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation.” Economic Journal, 37 (March): 47-61. Ranade, Rahul and M. Dinesh Kumar. 2004. “Narmada Water for Groundwater Recharge in North Gujarat: Conjunctive Management in Large Irrigation Projects.” Economic and Political Weekly 39 (July31): 3510-3513. 289 Rangarao, A.P. 2003. Report on role and efficiency of ANM and male worker in primary health care. Andhra Pradesh: A Qualitative Study funded by DFID. (Unpublished paper commissioned by DIFD, New Delhi, India). Rao, Hemlata. 2003. “Economic and Fiscal Impact of Royalty Rates of Coal and Lignite in India.” A Working Paper, Institute for Social and Economic Change, Bangalore. Rao, M. Govinda and Sudipto Mundie. 1992 “An Analysis of Changes in State Government Subsidies, 1997-98.” In State Finances in India A. Bagchi, J.L. Bajaj and W. Byrd eds. New Delhi: Vikas Publishers. Rao, M. Govinda. 1981. Political Economy of Tax and Expenditure Determination. New Delhi: Allied Publishers. Reddy, M.S, Waqif, A.A. 1988. “Non Tax Revenues.” In Multilevel Planning in India-Process and Perspectives, ed Reddy, Y V, and Kosalram, K., Centre for Economic and Social Studies, Hyderabad. Reddy, S., and J. Vandermoortele. 1996. “User Financing of Basic Social Services: A review of Theoretical Arguments and Empirical Evidence.” UNICEF Staff Working Paper, United Nations Children’s Fund, Evaluation, Policy and Planning Series, New York. Reserve Bank of India. 2005. State Finances: A Study of Budget, Various Issues, Mumbai. Rogers, Peter, Ramesh Bhatia and Annetta Huber. 1997. “Water as a Social and Economic Good: How to Put the Principle into Practice.” Global Water Partnership, Stockholm. Sachs, Jeffrey D. 2001. Macroeconomics and Health: Investing in Health for Economic Development, Report of the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health. World Health Organization, Geneva. Sakthivadivel, R., P. Gomathinayagam and Tushaar Shah. 2004. “Rejuvenating Local Tanks through Local Institutions.” Economic and Political Weekly: 39 (July 31): 35213526. Saleth, R.M. and A. Dinar. 1997. “Satisfying Urban Thirst, Water Supply Augmentation and Pricing Policy in Hyderabad City, India.” World Bank Technical Paper No. 395. Washington D.C. Samuelson, Paul A. 1954. “The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure”. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36 (4) Nov.: 387-389. Sanan, Deepak. 2004. “Delivering Basic Public Services in Himachal Pradesh is the Success Sustainable?” Economic and Political Weekly. 39 (February 28): 975-978. Sankar, Deepa and Vinish Kathuria. 2004. “Health Systems Performance in Rural India: Efficiency Estimates Across States.” Economic and Political Weekly 39 (March 27): 1427-1433. Sankar, U. 1992. Public Sector Pricing: Theory and Applications. Indian Economic Association Trust for Research and Development, New Delhi. ___. and Om Prakash Mathur. 1998. “Urban Water Supply ad Sanitation.” Economic Instruments for Environment Sustainability, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy. 290 Sauerborn, Rainer, Claude Bodart, and Rene Owona. 1993. “Provincial Revolving Drug Funds for the Recovery of Recurrent Health Service Costs in Cameroon.” A Development Discussion Paper No. 468, Harvard Institute for International Development, Harvard University, Massachusetts. Schantz, Radford, Jr. 1994. “Purpose and Effects of a Royalty on Public Land Minerals.” Resources Policy 20: 3548. Schmitz, P.W. 1997. “Monopolistic Provision of Excludable Public Goods under Private Information.” Public Finance 52: 89-101. Sepehri, Ardeshir and, Robert Chernomas. 2001. “Are User Charges Efficiency and Equity Enhancing? A Critical Review of Economic Literature with Particular Reference to Experience from Developing Countries.” Journal of International Development 13: 183-209. Shah, Tushaar and Christopher Scott. 2004. “Water Sector Reforms in Mexico: Lessons for India’s New Water Policy”, Economic and Political Weekly 39 (January 24): 361-370. Shah, Tushaar, Mark Giordano and Jinxia Wang. 2004. “Irrigation Institutions in a Dynamic Economy.” Economic and Political Weekly 39 (July 31): 3452-3461. Shetty, S.A. Finances of State Government in India (Sponsored by Planning Commission) I/II. Mumbai: EPW Research Foundation. Singh, Alaka. 2006. “Strengthening Health Systems to Meet MDGs.” The London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, London: Oxford University Press. Sinha, Sidharth. 2004. “Agricultural Insurance in India: Scope for Participation of Private Insurers”. Economic and Political Weekly. 39 (June 19): 2605-2612. Small, K. 1983. “The Incedence of Congenstion Tolls on Urban Highways.” Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 13: 90-111. Stephen, Bailey J. 1994.“User Charges for Urban Services.” Urban studies, Vol. 31(4/5): 745-765. Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2000. “Public Goods and Publicly Provided Private Goods.” Economics of the Public Sector, 3rd ed. New York: W.W. Norton & Company. Sundaram, K. 2006. “On Backwardness and Fair Access to Higher Education: Results from NSS 55th Round Surveys, 1999-2000.” Economic and Political Weekly, December 16-20: 5173-5182. Tan, J.P. 1985. “Private Education: Some Macro Trends on Enrollment and Expenditures.” International Review of Education. 3(1): 103-17. Tata Energy Research Institute. 2001. “Overview of Mining and Minerals Industry in India.” A Working Paper, New Delhi. Teles, Vladimir Kiihl and Joaquim P. Andrarde. 2004. “Public Investment in Basic Education and Economic Growth.” A Working Paper, Universidad de Brasilia, Department de Economic. Thobani, M. 1983. “Charging User Fees for Social Services-The Case of Education in Malawi.” World Bank Staff Working Paper No.572, Washington, D.C. Tilak, J.B.G. 1993. “Financing Higher Education in India: Principles, Practice and Policy Issues.” Higher Education. Netherlands. 26(1), July: 43-67. 291 ___. 1996. “How Free is Free Primary Education?” Economic and Political Weekly. 31 (February 10): 1996. ___. 2004. “Absence of Policy and Perspective in Higher Education”. Economic and Political Weekly 39 (May 22): 2159-2164. ___. 2004. “Public Subsidies in Education in India”. Economic and Political Weekly 39 (January 24): 343-359. Tooley, James. 2003. “Grants-in-aid Schools and Colleges in Karnataka”. Report Prepared for the World Bank. Train, Kenneth E., Moshe Ben-Akiva, Terry Atherton. 1989. “Consumption Patterns and Self-selecting Tariffs”. Review of Economics and Statistics, 71 (1): 62-67. United Nations (UN). 2006. “Enhancing Knowledge and Capacity”. In Water: A Shared Responsibility. The United Nations World Water Development Report 2. ___ Millennium Project. 2005. “Investing in development: A Practical Plan to Achieve the Millennium Development Goals.” London Earthscan. Available at http//www.unmillenniumproject.org Vaidyanathan, A. ----. “Irrigation Subsidies.” Madras Institute of Development Studies, Chennai. Wade, Robert. 1982. “Systems of Administrative and Political Corruption: Canal Irrigation in South India”. Journal of Development Studies. 18: 287-328. Wagner, Richard E. 1991. Ed. Charging for Government: User Charges and Earmarked Taxes in Principle and Practice. London and New York: Rutledge. Walters, A.A. 1968. “Economics of Road User Charges.” World Bank, staff occasional paper no.5, Washington, D.C. Wash, C. 1991. “Public Goods Provision with Price Exclusion: Market Behavior and Market Performance”. In Retrospective on Public Finance, ed. L. Eden, Duke, London University Press. World Bank. 1986. Financing Education in developing Countries: An Exploration of Policy Options. Washington, D.C., U.S.A. ___. 2002. India's Transport Sector: The Challenges Ahead. Volume I, Washington D.C. ___. 2004. “State Health System Development Projects II.” Implementation completion Report. Washington, D.C. ___. 2004. India Financing Highways: A Document. Report No. 30363-IN, Washington, D.C. ___. 2005. “An Invigorated Indian Water State for the 21st Century.” India’s Water Economy: Bracing for a Turbulent Future. A Report, Washington, D.C. ___. 2005. Kristin Komives – (et. Al.); with support from Roohi Abdullah “Water, Electricity and the Poor: Who Benefits from Utility Subsidies?” Direction and Development, Energy and Water Division, Washington, D.C. ___. 2005. State Fiscal Reforms in India: Progress and Prospects. New Delhi: Macmillan India Limited. 292 ___. 2006. India Water Supply and Sanitation: Bridging The Gap Between Infrastructure and Service. World Bank Report India Country Team, Energy and Infrastructure Department, South Asia Region, (January). World Development Report. 2003. Sustainable Development in a Dynamic World: Transforming Institutions, Growth, and Quality of Life. World Bank, Washington, D.C. ___. 2004. Making Services Work for Poor People. A publication of World Bank and Oxford University Press, Washington, D.C. 293