Standpunkt - Lazard Asset Management
Transcription
Standpunkt - Lazard Asset Management
Standpunkt Negative Leitzinsen – Ursachen und Folgen Mai 2016 Negative Leitzinsen – Ursachen und Folgen • Das globale BIP-Wachstum ist in den letzten Jahrzehnten stetig gefallen; besonders Kontinental- europa und Japan sind von Stagnation und Disinflation geplagt. • Seit der Finanzmarktkrise 2008 haben sich die Probleme verschärft. Wegen der hohen Verschuldung der meisten Länder und mangels struktureller Reformen hat die Geldpolitik die Rolle des einzigen Wachstumstreibers übernommen, häufig über unkonventionelle Geldpolitik wie quantitative Lockerung und direkte Marktinterventionen. • 2012 und in den folgenden Jahren haben die Zentralbanken in Dänemark, Schweden, Japan, Schweiz und der Eurozone schrittweise negative Einlagenzinsen eingeführt. Diese fünf Zentralbanken belasten die Geschäftsbanken mit Gebühren, wenn sie Reserven bei der Zentralbank halten. • ie Hauptmotivation für die unkonventionelle Geldpolitik war es, die bereits sehr großzügig versorD gende Geldpolitik weiter zu lockern, um den Abwärtstrend in den Inflationserwartungen zu stoppen. Die Zentralbanken wollen die Geschäftsbanken ermutigen (fast zwingen), ihre Kreditvergabe zu erhöhen und die Bedingungen der Kreditvergabe weiter zu lockern. • s gibt fünf Transmissionskanäle, über die der monetäre Stimulus negativer Zinsen das Wachstum E erhöhen soll: den Kreditkanal, den Vermögenskanal, den Portfolio- und Risikomanagement-Kanal, den Inflationierungskanal und den Wechselkursmechanismus. • Verschiedene Risiken und Nebenwirkungen könnten die positiven Effekte negativer Einlagenzinsen unterminieren, zumindest langfristig. Negative Zinsen erzeugen Fehlanreize für vernünftiges ökono- misches Verhalten, ermöglichen den Politikern Reformverweigerung in der Wirtschafts- und Finanzpolitik, erzeugen Marktverwerfungen, Fehlbewertungen und Stabilitätsrisiken, erhöhen die Ungleichheit von Vermögen und Einkommen und gefährden bei einem Scheitern das Vertrauen in unabhängige Zentralbanken, die Politiker, die Marktwirtschaft und letztendlich die Demokratie. • Es ist noch zu früh, um wirkliche Schlüsse aus den Erfahrungen mit negativen Leitzinsen zu ziehen, aber die ersten Eindrücke lassen vermuten, dass die unkonventionelle Geldpolitik nicht sehr effizient ist und die Finanzmärkte stärker beeinflusst als die Realwirtschaft. Es ist nicht übertrieben zu vermuten, dass die Zentralbanken Gefahr laufen, mit ihrer Politik Assetpreisblasen zu erzeugen, insbesondere im Fixed Income-Bereich, da etwa 40 % aller Staatsanleihen von Euroland-Emittenten gegenwärtig mit negativen Renditen gepreist sind. • Der desaströse Nettoeffekt der negativen Zinsen auf die Ertragssituation von Altersvorsorgeein- richtungen, Lebens- und Rentenversicherungen oder Geldmarktfonds ist ziemlich offensichtlich und gefährdet die Zukunft des gesamten Rentensystems. Der Nettoeffekt auf die Profitabilität der Banken ist nicht ganz so eindeutig, aber vermutlich ebenfalls negativ, zumal sich die Zins- strukturkurven in Folge der unkonventionellen Geldpolitik verflacht haben. Dies könnte das Banken- system weiter aushöhlen. ©2016. Herausgeber: Lazard Asset Management (Deutschland) GmbH, Neue Mainzer Straße 75, 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Deutschland (Selbstverlag). Alle Rechte vorbehalten. Bei Zitaten wird um Quellenangabe gebeten. Die in dieser Veröffentlichung enthaltenen Informationen beruhen auf öffentlich zugänglichen Quellen, die wir für zuverlässig halten. Eine G arantie für die Richtigkeit oder Vollständigkeit der Angaben können wir nicht übernehmen, und keine Aussage in diesem Bericht ist als s olche Garantie zu verstehen. Alle Meinungsaussagen geben die aktuelle Einschätzung des Verfassers/der Verfasser wieder und stellen nicht notwendigerweise die Meinung von Lazard oder deren assoziierter Unternehmen dar. Die in dieser Publikation zum Ausdruck gebrachten Meinungen können sich ohne vorherige Ankündigung ändern. Weder Lazard noch deren assoziierte Unternehmen übernehmen irgendeine Art von Haftung für die Verwendung dieser Publikation oder deren Inhalt. Weder diese Veröffentlichung noch ihr Inhalt noch eine Kopie dieser Veröffentlichung darf ohne die vorherige ausdrückliche Erlaubnis von Lazard auf irgendeine Weise verändert oder an Dritte verteilt oder übermittelt werden. Mit der Annahme dieser Veröffentlichung wird die Zustimmung zur Einhaltung der o.g. Bestimmungen gegeben. Negative Key Rates - Causes and Implications • Global nominal GDP growth rates have come down dramatically over the last decades. Especially continental Europe and Japan have a serious stagnation and disinflation problem. • Since the financial markets crisis in 2008, the problems have become more severe. Due to the high indebtedness of most countries and the lack of will for structural reforms, monetary policy has taken over the lonely role of reviving growth, often via unconventional monetary policy like quantitative easing and direct market interventions. • Starting in 2012, the central banks of Denmark, Sweden, Japan, Switzerland and the Eurozone crossed the Rubicon and introduced negative deposit rates. These five central banks are now charging commercial banks for their reserves at the central bank. • The main motivation for these unconventional policy steps was to further ease the accommodative monetary policy stance to fight the downward pressure on inflation expectations. Central banks want to encourage commercial banks to increase their loan portfolios, boosted by a general easing of credit conditions. • There are five interconnected monetary channels via which the monetary stimulus aims to lift growth: the credit channel, the asset valuation channel, the portfolio balance and risk taking channel, the reflation channel and the exchange rate channel. • Several risks could make negative nominal interest rates counterproductive, at least in the long run. They may cause disincentives for prudent economic behavior, facilitate reform fatigue among politicians, could generate market distortions and financial stability risks, increase income and wealth inequality and endanger confidence in (independent) central banks, politicians, the market economy and democracy in general. • It is still too early to gauge the experience with negative rates, but the first impressions seem to suggest these policy decisions are not very effective and have more influence on the financial markets than on the real economy. It is not completely exaggerated to suppose that the central banks risk to generate asset price bubbles, mainly in fixed income markets, as about 40% of all government bonds in the Eurozone have a negative yield at the moment. • The disastrous net effect of low or negative rates on pension funds, money market funds or insurance companies owing to falling asset income is quite obvious, but the net effect of the new decisions on the profitability of the banks is also most likely negative, especially as the yield curves have flattened dramatically after the decisions. The net interest margin for Eurozone banks has come down steadily in all business segments, which may reduce the supply of credit and hamper the financial intermediation. Lazard Asset Management Negative Key Rates - Causes and Implications In Japan, 10year nominal p.a. growth rates became negative for the first time in 2006 and could not recover decisively since then. In big parts of Europe, not more than 2% p.a. nominal growth over a decade became the norm. Due to the over-debtedness of both the private and the government sector in Japan and most European countries, the central banks became the only institutions able to act in order to generate an environment where these countries can grow again, especially as the preparedness of politicians to reform and deregulate has been undermined by the financial market crisis (see exhibit 2). Since reaching a top after WWII in the 1970ies, global nominal growth rates have fallen steadily, decade by decade, as both real growth and inflation came down dramatically. This long term trend to economic stagnation combined with disinflation was visible everywhere, but was the most pronounced in Japan and continental Europe (see exhibit 1). Exhibit 1: Nominal Growth Globally 10Y nominal GDP growth, p.a., rolling 16 16 14 14 Exhibit 2: Government Debt Japan and Eurozone, Gross Government Indebtedness, in % GDP 12 12 0 10 10 100 50 8 22,9% Portugal 6 6 89,8% Italy 79,8% Cyprus 4 4 2 2 0 0 52,7% Spain 1960 1965 1970 1975 USA, last 2,9 Switzerland, last 2,1 1980 1985 UK, last 3 Japan, last -0,1 1990 1995 2000 France, last 2 Netherlands, last 2 2005 2010 2015 Germany 11,0% Netherlands As of 4 May 2016 Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream 67,6% 9,4% Finland 62,4% 18,4% 0 86,2% 83,3% 61,3% 71,0% Slovenia Italy, last 0,79 108,7% 95,2% 48,6% 19,7% 132,6% 128,8% 96,8% 36,8% Austria 178,4% 99,0% 36,5% Ireland 250 106,3% Belgium -8,1% France 200 245,4% 109,8% Greece 8 150 Japan 50 Gross Government Debt 100 150 200 250 Change since 1999 As of 4 May 2016 Politicians did not easily accept this “new normal” of low growth and low inflation. With a combination of deregulation and releveraging of the world economy, they tried to refuel the “animal spirits” of companies, entrepreneurs and investors since the 1980ies. Governments felt more and more responsible for growth and employment and did all they could to help the global economy to grow. Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream Which Central Banks Did Introduce Negative Rates? Since the financial market crisis in 2008, monetary policy has become hyper-expansionary everywhere to counter-balance the effects of private deleveraging and the burden of high government debt. Unconventional monetary policy and the expansion of central bank balance sheets via quantitative easing has become the norm in the USA, Japan, Europe and (with constraints) China in the post crisis era (see exhibit 3). The success of this economic growth policy, though, was limited despite the “fall of the wall 1989” and all his positive consequences for growth and inflation, and ended with the financial market crisis in 2008. Since then, the world continued to lose its mojo, as there was and currently still is a strong political pressure to re-regulate, deleverage and to reduce government debt. This pressure is the most pronounced in Japan and Europe, just in a time when the problems with demographics start to hit these regions. 4 Standpunkt May 2016 What is the expected transmission mechanism of negative key rates? Exhibit 3: Central Bank Assets in Mrd. E u ro Global Central Banks, Total Assets Indexed (2003=100) 800 800 700 700 600 600 500 500 400 400 300 300 200 200 100 100 0 The main motivation for these decisions was to further ease the already accommodative monetary policy stance to fight the growing threat of deflation amid downward pressure on inflation expectations, to deter capital flows and to prevent local currencies from appreciating. The five central banks are now charging commercial banks for their (excess) reserves at the central bank. Negative deposit rates should provide some encouragement to banks to buy alternative assets and to increase their loan portfolios, hence to put downward pressure on yields and borrowing costs. This would be transmitted through the economy by a general easing of credit conditions.2 In more detail, central banks mention five interconnected monetary channels via which the monetary stimulus of negative rates aims to lift (short-term) growth3: 0 2004 2006 FED 2008 ECB BOJ 2010 2012 People’s Bank of China 2014 2016 SNB As of 4 May 2016 • The credit channel: Negative interest rates shall deter saving, discourage banks from holding (excess) reserves and encourage borrowing. Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream • The asset valuation channel: Negative interest rates boost asset prices by reducing the discount rate on future cash flows from assets, making these more valuable. However, although central banks reduced interest rates rapidly and printed money as if there were no tomorrow, zero interest rates were always widely perceived to be an effective lower bound. There were limited experiences with negative key rates in a special situation by the Swiss National Bank in the 1970s, but apart from that short period the zero lower bound was regarded as some kind of Rubicon that no-one wanted to pass. • The portfolio balance and risk taking channel: Negative interest rates encourage investors to shift out of low risk assets into riskier and less liquid assets. • The reflation channel: Negative interest rates are planned to ward off the risk of debt deflation by boosting inflation expectations. This has changed in July 2012 when the Danish central bank introduced negative deposit rates (currently the most important key rate) for the first time, followed later by the central banks of Switzerland, Sweden, Japan and the Eurozone, with money market rates following suit into negative territory (see exhibit 4).1 • The exchange rate channel: Negative interest rates change financial market flows, thus depreciate the currency to boost net exports, growth, employment and inflation. Exhibit 4: Money Market Rates What are theoretical side effects of negative keyrates? 3M Money Market Rates 6 6 5 5 4 4 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 0 There are several different risks that could make negative nominals interest rates counterproductive, at least in the long run. 1. Disincentives: The interest rate is the price of capital in the economy. With interest rates on artificially low or negative levels, the price mechanism loses its function. If borrowing becomes a free lunch, it generates incentives for corporations, other ins- titutions and especially the government to borrow too much. Therefore, the borrowers get a disincentive for fiscal discipline and rational, prudent economic behaviour. 2. Reform fatigue: The unlimited help of central banks for every- one undermines the pressure on governments, banks and compa- nies to focus on structural reforms, balance sheet consolidation and efficiency. Therefore, decisions on real economic policy challenges are delayed, the real growth potential, productivity and capital investments weakened. -1 -1 2000 2002 Sweden, last -0,4 Denmark, last -0,17 2004 2006 2008 2010 Eurozone, last -0,18 Switzerland, last -0,7294 2012 2014 2016 Japan, last -0,24 As of 4 May 2016 Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream 5 Lazard Asset Management 3. Market distortion: Central bank money and interventions have become the main drivers of capital markets returns that dominate fundamentals in setting market valuations. This destroys the risk management aspect of financial markets, increases the risk of bubbles and may cause the crowding out of real economy investments in favor of pure (momentum driven) financial market investments. In general it seems that the transmission of negative policy rates works to some extent and the technical, infrastructure and operational problems have remained limited.6 Growth of currency in circulation has picked up a bit, but cash hoarding per se has not been observed, yet. This may be a sign that the ultimate effective lower bound has not been reached, yet. This view is confirmed by the fact that the gold price was also boosted a bit by negative interest rates, but is still far away from discounting real stress, disaster or a borderline situation. 4. Financial Stability Risks: Negative interest rates destroy not only the business models of financial institutions like insurance companies, money markets funds, asset management firms, banks and companies’ pension funds, but undermine the pension systems of entire countries. In a low return / high costs and regulation world, all these institutions are unable to meet their obligations or reach their long term net return targets. This disruption implies substantial risks to the solvability of these institutions and finally financial stability, especially as the effects of demographic shifts endanger the financial system anyway. However, looking at the real economy, on growth, inflation, current account balances, employment or productivity, we can state that monetary policy had a limited effect in the last years, as real numbers did only change modestly, since the central banks introduced these unconventional policy steps. Growth and inflation continued to remain low globally, as the reflationary impulse of the policy measures was mainly counter-balanced by the strong effect of collapsing oil and commodity prices. Inflation remained low and was neither replaced by rising inflation nor did we experience deflation, and inflation expectations continued to slide at least in the Eurozone (see exhibit 5). 5. Inequality: Many empirical studies suggest that negative interest rates increase income and wealth inequality in the society. Most households will lose from the shrinking returns on their savings, as the main losers of unorthodox monetary policy are small savers, pensioners and life insurance policy holders. The winners are the most highly indebted economic institutions like governments or a limited number of companies, but also many ultra-rich that may use the service of sophisticated asset managers to realize capital gains in financial markets, private equity, private debt, infrastructure projects, real assets or in real estate.4 Exhibit 5: Global Inflation Expectations Inflation Linked Swap, 10Y 6. Loss of Confidence: Central Banks are perceived as having taken over responsibility for the whole economy and the stability of the political and societal system, especially in the Eurozone and Japan. If the unconventional monetary policy fails or cannot fulfill all the promises in terms of growth, employment or wealth, the outcome could not only destroy the central banks’ credibility, but undermine confidence in the market economy and democra cy in general. Real Life Experience with Negative Interest Rates 4,0 4,0 3,5 3,5 3,0 3,0 2,5 2,5 2,0 2,0 1,5 1,5 1,0 1,0 0,5 0,5 2007 2008 USD 2009 EUR 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 GBP As of 4 May 2016 It is still early days in terms of gauging the experience with negative rates, and more time may be needed to make a full assessment. It may be the case that the duration of negative rates may matter, as the change of behavior or financial innovations to react to such structural changes normally take an extended period of time. Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream When we look at the financial markets, the influence of unconventional monetary policy has been much clearer and more pronounced. Since 2009, most asset classes have been in a permanently rising trend and it is not completely exaggerated to suppose that the central banks at least risk generating multiple asset price bubbles, obviously mainly in all fixed income markets. The current valuation can be easier explained by monetary policy decisions than by fundamentals, as about 40% of all government bonds in the Eurozone have a negative yield at the moment (see exhibit 6 and 7) However, at least until now, both the positive and the negative effects of artificially low or negative interest rates have been more limited than expected in advance.5 As with quantitative easing of central banks in general, it is difficult to separate the effects of monetary policy from all the other input factors in the global economy. In contrast to physics or other sciences, it is not possible to test models or ideas via experiments and we do not know what would have happened if monetary policy would have acted differently. 6 Standpunkt May 2016 Exhibit 6: Performance of Asset Classes Exhibit 8: Steepness of the Yield Curve of the Eurozone Performance of Asset Classes German 2Y Schatz Yields and Yield Curve Steepness since 01/01/2009, in EUR, % -50 0 50 100 150 200 3,0 10 250 227,7% ML Euro HY S&P 500 222,7% 2,5 164,9 % MSCI World FTSE Global Core Infrastructure 8 156,3% 148,9 % BofA ML EM Corporate Plus 2,0 143,4% EMBI Global Div Global Cat Bonds 116,9 % Nikkei 115,3% 112,5% MSCI EM 6 95,5% 85,9 % 85,8% UK 10Y Govt 85,7% Italy 10Y Govt 80,6% Spain 10Y Govt 76,3% Gold 73,5% Silver 1,5 1,0 4 0,5 68,1% France 10Y Govt Steepness 2Y Schatz Yield 106,4% DA X Copper MSCI EMU 59,9 % GBI-EM Global Div 2 59,0% iBoxx Euro Corp 0,0 58,4% Germany 10Y Govt 57,9 % US 10Y Govt 53,5% Barclays Global Aggregate 46,2% iBoxx Euro Govt 43,7% iBoxx Euro Covered Germany 5Y Bobl 31,6% Japan 10Y Govt 31,2% -0,5 0 19,1% Brent -1,0 9,2% Germany 2Y Schatz Euro Trade Weighted 7,0% Citigroup 3M Money Market TR 3,9 % -2 1990 -4,8% CRB Commodities -50 0 50 100 150 200 1992 1994 1996 1998 2Y Schatz Yield, last -0,488 250 2000 2002 2004 2006 Steepness 5Y-2Y, last 0,093 As of 4 May 2016 As of 4 May 2016 Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Steepness 10Y-2Y, last 0,685 Negative Interest Rates and the Financial Sector Exhibit 7: Share of Negative Yielding Eurozone Government Bonds Bonds with negative yields in the iBoxx EUR Sovereigns in % of the index 40 40 35 35 30 30 25 25 20 20 15 15 10 10 5 5 0 0 One of the discussion points is the importance of negative key rates on the profitability of the financial sector. While the negative consequences of low rates on pension funds, money market funds or insurance companies owing to falling asset income is quite obvious, the consequences for banks are more complicated. However, the price development of bank stocks globally in the last years seems to suggest that unconventional monetary policy at least did not solve the banks’ problems since the financial market crisis (see exhibit 9). Exhibit 9: Relative Performance of Bank Stocks Bank Stocks: Relative Performance to the Regional Index 2014 2015 2016 As of 26 April 2016 110 110 100 100 90 90 80 80 70 70 60 60 50 50 40 40 Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream What we also can observe is that the efficiency of these unconventional monetary policy decisions has come down dramatically over time. The introduction of negative interest rates as the preliminary last step of these decisions did not move currencies very much and the effect of the shape of the yield curve as an indicator of a reflationary impulse did not exist at all. In the contrary, since the ECB and others have introduced negative interest rates, the currencies have stabilized and the yield curve has flattened (see exhibit 8). 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 MSCI EUROPE COML BANKS $ - RI/MSCI EUROPE U$ - RI S&P500 BANKS - RI/S&P 500 COMPOSITE - RI JAPAN-DS Banks/JAPAN-DS Market As of 4 May 2016 Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream 7 2013 2014 2015 Lazard Asset Management On the one side, negative deposit rates impose a cost on banks with excess reserves, thus they erode the bank profitability by narrowing banks’ net interest rate margins. As banks are (until now) unwilling to pass through negative deposit rates to their (retail) customers to avoid the erosion of their customer base and to protect profits (only large deposits from firms and institutional investors are extensively paying negative interest rates), the gap between commercial banks’ lending and deposit rates is shrinking.7 Exhibit 10: Euro Area Margin Survey Additionally, the yield curves have flattened in the last years (i.e. term premiums came down) despite all the easing measures. Central bank asset purchases have depressed yields at the long end. As a consequence, banks earn less on long term loans relative to their short term funding, but also extra returns available from taking on riskier assets have fallen. The result is that the margins of standard banking maturity transformation have been compressed, making it more difficult to rebuild their capital positions from earnings. The ECB’s new TLTROs at potentially negative rates may be intended to offset the erosion of bank net interest margins in the Eurozone, but will only partially counterbalance the problem.8 80 80 60 60 40 40 20 20 0 0 -20 -40 -20 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 LOAN SVY: NET EFFECT OF MARGIN ON AVERAGE CREDIT TO FIRMS : Euro Zone LOAN SVY: NET EFFECT - AVERAGE HOUSING CREDIT & MARGINS : Euro Zone 2016 -40 As of 4 May 2016 Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream To defend profitability, the banks may choose to borrow less from the central bank, in order to lower excess reserves and avoid the negative deposit rates. This could put upwards pressure on rates on the interbank and bond markets, offsetting the stimulating impact of the negative deposit rates. The banks could try to defend their margins by increasing their lending interest rates, for example for mortgage loans. They also could see negative rates as incentive to shrink, not grow. Banks may be encouraged to look for opportunities overseas rather inside their home markets. Summary and Outlook Global nominal GDP growth rates have come down dramatically over the last decades, as both real GDP growth and inflation manifested a clear downtrend. Neither fiscal, nor economic or monetary policy was able to stop this trend despite many efforts that have been made. Especially continental Europe and Japan have been confronted with a serious stagnation and disinflation problem. On the other, more positive side, banks can realize capital gains on the sale of their government bonds to central banks and bolster their capital position and their capacity to extend loans. Since the financial markets crisis in 2008, the problems have become even more severe. Due to the high indebtedness of most countries and the lack of will for structural reforms, monetary policy has taken over the lonely role of reviving growth. Unconventional monetary policy like quantitative easing and direct market interventions have become the norm in the last years. The net effect of ultra-low or negative key rates is not completely clear, but the BIS and the ECB’s Euro Era bank lending survey show that the net interest margin for Eurozone banks has come down steadily in all business segments, which may reduce the supply of credit and hamper the financial intermediation (see exhibit 10). Starting in 2012, the central banks of Denmark, Sweden, Japan, Switzerland and the Eurozone even crossed the Rubicon and introduced negative deposit rates for the first time in history (with the exception of Switzerland in the 1970s in a very special situation). These five central banks are now charging commercial banks for their reserves at the central bank. The main motivation for these unconventional policy steps was to further ease the accommodative monetary policy stance to fight the downward pressure on inflation expectations by deterring capital flows and by weakening the local currencies. Central banks want to encourage commercial banks to increase their loan portfolios, boosted by a general easing of credit conditions. 8 Standpunkt May 2016 Central banks mention five interconnected monetary channels via which the monetary stimulus aims to lift growth: the credit channel, the asset valuation channel, the portfolio balance and risk taking channel, the reflation channel and the exchange rate channel. Weitere Lazard Publikationen Central banks must be aware that several risks could make negative nominal interest rates counterproductive, at least in the long run. This unconventional monetary policy may cause disincentives for prudent economic behavior, facilitate reform fatigue among politicians, could generate market distortions and financial stability risks, increase income and wealth inequality and endanger confidence in central banks, politicians and democracy in general. Standpunkt Juli 2012 Hintergrund Juni 2012 „Aktieninvestments als Inflationsschutz, Teil 2” „Inflationsindexierte Anleihen” Hintergrund September 2012 „Investieren in Infrastruktur – Lazard Global Listed Infrastructure” Standpunkt Juni 2013 It is still too early to gauge the experience with negative rates, but the first impressions seem to suggest these policy decisions are not very effective and have more influence on the financial markets than on the real economy. It is not completely exaggerated to suppose that the central banks at least risk to generate multiple asset price bubbles, obviously mainly in fixed income markets, as about 40% of all government bonds in the Eurozone have a negative yield at the moment. „Boulevard der Dämmerung – ein Zwischenbericht zur Entwicklung der Europäischen Währungsunion” Hintergrund August 2013 „Emerging Markets Corporate Bonds” Hintergrund September 2013 „Globale Renten, Währungsmanagement und Benchmarks” The disastrous net effect of low or negative rates on pension funds, money market funds or insurance companies owing to falling asset income is quite obvious, but the net effect of the new decisions on the profitability of the banks is also most likely negative, especially as the yield curves have flattened dramatically after the decisions. The net interest margin for Eurozone banks has come down steadily in all business segments, which may reduce the supply of credit and hamper the financial intermediation. Standpunkt November 2013 „Investmentrestriktionen, Risikobudgets und Anlageerfolg” Standpunkt März 2014 „Kapitalanlagen im Zeitalter des Euro” Standpunkt Mai 2014 „Warum Emerging Markets Debt Investments?” Verfasser: Werner Krämer Tel: 069 / 50606–140 Hintergrund Juni 2014 „Alternative Indizes im Asset Management?” Standpunkt August 2014 Literaturverzeichnis „Kollateralschäden - über die unerwünschten Nebenwirkungen hyperexpansiver Geldpolitik?” M. Bech / A. Malkhozov: How have central banks implemented negative policy rates, BIS Quarterly Review, March 2016, S. 31-45. 1 Hintergrund März 2015 World Bank: Negative Interest Rates in Europe, World Bank Global Economic Outlook, June 2015, p. 13-25. 2 „Smart Beta – Alter Wein in neuen Schläuchen?” H. Hannoun: Ultra-low or negative interest rates: what they mean for financial stability and growth, BIS Euro Finance High Level Seminar, Riga, 22.4.2015. 3 Hintergrund April 2015 K. Adam / P. Tzamourani: Distributional consequences of asset price inflation in the euro area, Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper, no. 27/2015. 4 „Indexbenchmarks für Emerging Markets Debt” O. Adler: Negative interest rates one year on, Credit Suisse, Investment Strategy & Research, Monitor Switzerland, December 2015. 5 Hintergrund Mai 2015 H. Jackson: The International Experience with Negative Policy Rates, Bank of Canada Staff Discussion Paper, 2015-13. 6 „New Kids of the Bank – CoCo-Anleihen” C. M. Jensen / M. Spange: Interest Rate Pass-Through and the Demand for Cash at Negative Interest Rates, Danmark National Bank Monetary Review, Q2-2015, S. 1-12. 7 8 Hintergrund August 2015 N. Andrews: No relief for European banks, GavekalResearch Daily Paper, April 12, 2016. „Vom Charme aktiven Portfolio Managements” Hintergrund März 2016 „Tracking Error und Active Share – Alles aktiv oder was? ” Diese und weitere Publikationen stehen Ihnen als kostenloser Download auf unserer Homepage zur Verfügung: http://www.lazardnet.com/wissen 9 10 Lazard Asset Management (Deutschland) GmbH www.lazardnet.de Neue Mainzer Straße 75 60311 Frankfurt Tel.: 069 - 50 60 6 - 0 Fax: 069 - 50 60 6 - 100 Neuer Wall 9 20354 Hamburg Tel.: 040 - 35 72 90 - 20 Fax: 040 - 35 72 90 - 29