Monetary policy divergence
Transcription
Monetary policy divergence
Monetary policy divergence – a new transitory regime for global central banks Investment Forum Martin Hochstein Senior Strategist, Global Economics & Strategy, AllianzGI Over the course of the Great Financial Crisis, global central banks became the main policy actors to address both unprecedented stability risks to the financial system and the deepest global recession since the Great Depression of the 1930s. In response, monetary authorities have cut their policy rates more than 600 times during the past seven and a half years and also introduced a wide range of unconventional policy measures to overcome the assumed zero lower bound of interest rates. Divergent monetary policy landscape Following this long lasting period of broad based stimulus, the initial rate hike by the Federal Reserve at the end of last year finally kicked off a new episode of monetary policy divergence, an important investment theme that may contribute to higher economic and financial market volatility over the months ahead. Global monetary policy is expected to become more divergent in 2016. In order to classify the anticipated divergent strategies and related rationales, we pigeonholed the major central banks in the industrialized and emerging world into different categories. The tightening end of this new policy spectrum is represented by a group called “unconventional normalizers”, which basically comprises the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England. Why do we label them as “unconventional normalizers”? Normalizers, because the gradual rate hikes expected by both central banks over the course of this year constitute a slow withdrawal of monetary stimulus and a first step towards a medium-term normalization of their policies, but not restrictive policy actions per se. Unconventional, because both central banks already announced that they won’t follow the common course of action and scale back their bloated balance sheets first before raising interest rates, but to maintain huge amounts of excess reserves in the banking system well into the hiking cycle instead. While the current “low growth, low inflation, strong dollar” environment puts a question mark on the Federal Reserve’s ability to deliver the full 100 basis points of rate hikes, recently indicated by the median projections of FOMC participants for 2016, we nevertheless expect a steeper hiking path than currently priced into the money market curve. The Bank of England, on the other hand, will probably start raising its base rate at some point later this year, in light of a further tightening of the labor market and gradually Monetary policy divergence – a new transitory regime for global central banks Chart 1: Central bank landscape – 2015 vs. 2016 unconventional conventional USA 2015 Mexico South Africa United Kingdom tightening tightening 2016 Brazil Canada USA United Kingdom Switzerland Russia China easing Australia India Russia South Africa Mexico Canada Australia India Japan Euroland China conventional Switzerland Japan Euroland easing policy stance Brazil unconventional policy tools Source: Allianz Global Investors Global Economics & Strategy, December 2015 higher inflation rates. But Governor Mark Carney emphasized again more recently that the central bank wants to see the preconditions of above-trend growth, increasing domestic cost pressure and rising core inflation to be met beforehand. At the easing side of the spectrum are the ECB and the Bank of Japan, whose strategies continue to be dominated by lingering disinflation fears. Both are expected to deliver more policy stimulus, even beyond what’s already decided if necessary, in order to address potential risks of a de-anchoring of medium-term inflation expectations due to a persistent undershooting of their inflation objectives. Several other central banks, the so called forced followers, will be highly contingent upon the policy actions of either of these two groups in 2016. The Banco de Mexico, the South African Reserve Bank and the Hong Kong Monetary Authority are among those who have already raised policy rates in response to the Federal Reserve and will have to move in concert with the US central bank, either in order to uphold their currency peg or to avoid even more severe FX weakness and related disruptions in capital flows. On the other hand, some of the smaller European central banks, namely the Swiss National Bank, the Danish National Bank and the Swedish Riksbank might be forced to deliver even more targeted easing to shield their currencies against an unwanted appreciation as a side effect of the expansionary ECB policy. ◀ easing tightening ▶ Chart 2: Different rationales for divergent monetary policy actions Group Rationale Central banks Unconventional normalizers Gradual rate hikes in response to closing output gaps but no immediate shrinkage of central banks’ balance sheet. US, UK Forced followers Central banks in lockstep with US Fed in order to avoid severe FX weakness or disruptions in capital flows. Mexico, South Africa, Turkey, Hong Kong Idiosyncratics Policy mainly dominated by domestic factors. Terms-of-trade victims Ongoing accommodation to deal with the aftereffects of commodity price weakness and related income shocks. Canada, Australia, New Zealand, Norway, Russia Forced followers Targeted easing to avoid unwanted FX appreciation spilling over from expansive ECB policy. Denmark, Switzerland, Sweden Disinflation fighters More policy stimulus to address persistent undershooting of inflation objectives. Eurozone, Japan Brazil China, India Source: Allianz Global Investors Global Economics & Strategy, December 2015 2 Monetary policy divergence – a new transitory regime for global central banks Another group, the terms-of-trade victims, is also expected to maintain a highly accommodative policy stance or even deliver more stimulus in the months ahead. These countries, in particular Canada, Australia, New Zealand and Norway, are still grappling with the aftereffects of tumbling commodity prices and the related shock to their national incomes. Finally, there are those idiosyncratic central banks that will be primarily driven by domestic considerations over the course of this year. The People’s Bank of China, in particular, is expected to continue following its current course and support the ongoing restructuring of the Chinese economy with additional monetary stimulus in order to mitigate potential downside risks. The Banco Central do Brasil, on the other hand, is confronted with a deep recession but also rampant inflation and risks of a further de-anchoring of inflation expectations. Hence, the policy stance of the BCB remains skewed towards more tightening and much needed monetary tailwind might be still some way off in Brazil. Chart 3: G-5 monetary base will continue to expand in 2016 monetary base (% of world GDP) 24 20 16 12 8 4 0 2006 2008 US 2010 Eurozone 2012 Japan 2014 UK 2016 China Source: Allianz Global Investors Global Economics & Strategy, Bloomberg, December 2015 Emperors with no clothes: Are global central banks running short of policy options? It’s obvious that global central banks have started to navigate their policies in different directions. Nevertheless, we have to stress that, on a global scale, monetary policy will remain highly accommodative for the foreseeable future. The combined monetary base in G-5 countries (US, Eurozone, Japan, UK and China), for example, is expected to continue growing at a brisk pace in 2016. But increasing policy divergence will contribute to higher macroeconomic uncertainties going forward and might therefore also lead to rising volatility in financial markets. One of the most widely discussed monetary policy topics remains the question as to whether global central banks are at risk of running short of policy options. A glance at Europe illustrates that several central banks are already operating with a multitude of unconventional measures including full-blown quantitative easing, negative policy rates and also outright interventions in FX markets. Chart 4: Europe – unconventional policy at work Europe Sweden Forward guidance Long term refi operations Sovereign bond purchases Non-sovereign bond purchases Negative policy rates Switzerland % of total market volume 50 0.375 19 0.50 Primary objective Easier financial conditions FX interventions 25 Denmark Weaker currency 1,0 38 28 16 25 0,5 0 0 –0.10 –25 –0.30 –0,5 –0.35 –0.65 –50 US UK JAP Central bank sovereign bond holdings EUR SWE % Measure DEN –0.75 –1,0 SWI Policy rate (rs) Source: Allianz Global Investors Global Economics & Strategy, Bloomberg, January 2016 Note: Central bank sovereign bond holdings comprise current holding (US, UK) and expected holdings (EUR by March 2017; SWE by mid-2016, JAP by end-2016). 3 Monetary policy divergence – a new transitory regime for global central banks After having resorted to such a broad array of unconventional measures, what else could be done if more stimulus becomes necessary down the road? The good news is that within the current unconventional toolkit the effective lower bound of interest rates has not been tested yet. The predominant assumption in financial markets until three years ago was that policy rates could not be lowered into negative territory, because banks and depositors would evade the resulting penalty by converting their book money into cash. However, there are several reasons why this kind of cash preference hasn’t materialized so far, even in countries like Denmark and Switzerland where the relevant policy rates are currently at –0.65 and –0.75 %. While storage, transportation and other convenience costs still suppress the appetite for cash, commercial banks have also been hesitant to pass on negative interest rates to their retail depositors. As the effective lower bound is obviously below zero and has not been reached so far, policy makers might feel tempted to reduce policy rates even more into negative territory, in particular if they want to engineer further currency weakness. In a blunt way, that objective may also be achievable by directly intervening in the FX market. But this is neither an appropriate global policy tool, as the beggar-thy-neighbor problem and related fears of pernicious currency wars show, nor is it a sustainable strategy for individual countries under certain circumstances, as the turmoil caused by the abandoning of the Franc floor by the Swiss National Bank in early 2015 demonstrates. According to several research studies, the effective lower bound of policy rates might be as low as –2 to –3 %. Furthermore, there is still wiggle room left in many countries to extend quantitative easing by deepening and broadening the targeted universe of central banks’ bond purchases. But the rising share of sovereign bonds held by monetary authorities has raised the risk of stronger fiscal and political interference into monetary policy and may increasingly compromise the independence of central banks going forward. The Bank of Japan, for example, is expected to hold almost 40 % of the outstanding stock of Japanese government bonds by the end of this year. No wonder that analysts and investors have started to speculate if and when certain central banks might be forced to mull over some form of hidden debt monetization, for example by rolling over maturing government bond holdings on their balance sheet indefinitely. At the current juncture, this has to be considered as a “nuclear option” for central banks, not least due to the prevailing political and legal restrictions on monetary financing of public debt. The same holds true for other widely discussed proposals like the raising of central banks’ inflation targets, the introduction of so called helicopter money or even the abolition of cash or the devaluation of paper money to overcome the limits emanating from the effective lower bound of interest rates. Nevertheless, it becomes increasingly obvious that central banks, while already acting in uncharted territory, may be forced to deploy even more innovative measures in the future. But this would not come without risks! Further unconventional stimulus might, at a certain point, lead to heightened financial instability and could finally undermine the trust in the fiat money system more generally. Chart 5: Significant divergence between market expectations and median FOMC projections 10 8 6 % 4 2 0 –2 –4 –6 –8 Taylor rate = 3,96 + 1,42* inflation gap (core PCE) + 1,79 * output gap (NAIRU) 1987 1991 Fed funds target rate pre-GFC Taylor rule 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011 2015 Taylor rate (core PCE, NAIRU) median projection of FOMC participants implicit fed funds rate Source: Allianz Global Investors Global Economics & Strategy, Bloomberg, January 2016 4 Monetary policy divergence – a new transitory regime for global central banks See Blanchard / Dell’Ariccia / Mauro (2010), “Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy”. Ball (2014), “The Case for a LongRun Inflation Target of Four Percent” 1 Box: “Nuclear options” of unconventional monetary policy Raising of central banks’ inflation target. A higher inflation target, as suggested by several economists (most notably former IMF chief economist Olivier Blanchard1), would in theory ease the constraints on policy makers arising from the effective lower bound of interest rates. However, the benefit of more monetary policy flexibility might be more than offset by the costs arising from higher inflation volatility and the risk of a de-anchoring of inflation expectations. “Helicopter money”2. Nobel laureate Milton Friedman laid out the basic principle of a permanent and irreversible increase of a central bank’s monetary base to finance fiscal stimulus as early as 19693. It’s essentially like “dropping free money out of a helicopter”. Abolition or devaluation of paper money. The rising preference for zero-yielding cash in times of negative interest rates on deposits acts as a limit for more monetary policy accommodation. In order to address this problem, economists have been discussing several solutions such as a devaluation of paper money (for example by introducing a stamp duty on notes as initially suggested by the German economist Silvio Gesell4 more than a hundred years ago), different conversion rates between low denomination notes / electronic currency and large denomination notes or even the outright abolition of cash5. The resulting hike and reverse scenario would be clearly detrimental to many asset classes. In our central scenario we foresee an increasingly divergent but globally still highly accommodative monetary policy environment in 2016. Even those central banks which are expected to hike policy rates, in particular the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England, will deliberately remain “behind the curve” and leave interest rates way below levels indicated by their historical reaction functions, confirming our longstanding “lower for longer” and “financial repression” investment themes. But it goes without saying that the uncertain macroeconomic environment leaves ample room for monetary policy errors: Monetary policy exhaustion. Even in countries where more monetary stimulus is delivered, the marginal impact of those measures might subside further or they could become completely ineffective This kind of monetary policy exhaustion is a serious concern for policy makers. Hike and reverse. Central banks might face a situation in which their economy is incapable to digest even small rate hikes or in which financial markets have become so addicted to the liquidity provision that a policy normalization is impossible. See Friedman (1969), “The Optimum Quantity of Money” 3 See Gesell (1891), „Die Reformation im Münzwesen als Brücke zum Sozialen Staat“. Ilgmann (2011), “Silvio Gesell: ‘a strange, unduly neglected’ monetary theorist” 4 See Agarwal / Kimball (2015), ”Breaking through the Zero Lower Bound“. Rogoff (2014), “Costs and benefits of phasing out paper currency” 5 Ample room for monetary policy errors Expectations mismanagement. Even if central banks are able to follow their communicated strategy, they may be unable to steer market expectations accordingly. We currently observe this kind of expectations mismatch in the United States, where money markets are significantly underpricing the published median rate hike projections by FOMC participants. This heightens the risk of a rapid repricing later in the cycle. See Buiter (2014), “The Simple Analytics of Helicopter Money: Why It Works – Always” 2 Too low for too long. On the other hand, central banks might just overdo it and maintain their accommodative policy stance for too long, disregarding potential inflation risks. This would subsequently necessitate a rapid tightening of monetary conditions, which by itself could be enough to spark off turmoil in financial markets or trigger a recession. Fed Chair Janet Yellen alluded to this risk at the December FOMC press conference, arguing for an “earlier but slow” instead of a “later but fast” rate hike approach by the Federal Reserve. Overreliance on micro and macroprudential measures. Global central banks are increasingly relying on micro and macroprudential measures to address financial stability risks and exaggerations in asset markets nurtured by their easy policy stance. Those measures are still untested in a crisis situation and might spell trouble for policy makers if they don’t work as expected. 5 Monetary policy divergence – a new transitory regime for global central banks Act All the uncertainties and risks mentioned above point to a lower macroeconomic and monetary policy visibility over the months ahead. As a consequence, a more tactical and flexible investment approach seems to be appropriate from an investor’s perspective. In order to reap attractive asset returns in such an environment, active investing remains key. Imprint Allianz Global Investors GmbH Bockenheimer Landstr. 42 – 44 60323 Frankfurt am Main Global Capital Markets & Thematic Research Hans-Jörg Naumer (hjn), Ann-Katrin Petersen (akp), Stefan Scheurer (st) Allianz Global Investors www.twitter.com/AllianzGI_VIEW Data origin – if not otherwise noted: Thomson Financial Datastream. Calendar date of data – if not otherwise noted: February 2015 6 Further Publications of Global Capital Markets & Thematic Research Active Management →→ “It‘s the economy, stupid!” Alternatives →→ The Case for Alternatives →→ The Changing Nature of Equity Markets and the Need for More Active Management →→ Volatility as an Asset Class →→ Harvesting risk premium in equity investing →→ Active Management →→ Market-neutral equity strategies – Generating returns throughout the market cycle →→ Active Share: The Parts Are Worth More Than The Whole →→ Benefiting from Merger Arbitrage Financial Repression →→ Shrinking mountains of debt Capital Accumulation – Riskmanagement – Multi Asset →→ Smart risk with multi-asset solutions →→ QE Monitor →→ Sustainably accumulating wealth and capital income →→ Between a flood of liquidity and a drought on the government bond markets →→ Strategic Asset Allocation in Times of Financial Repression →→ Liquidity – The Underestimated Risk →→ The Long and Short of Volatility Investing →→ Macroprudential policy – necessary, but not a panacea Behavioral Finance →→ Behavioral Risk – Outsmart yourself! Strategy and Investment →→ Equities – the “new safe option“ for portfolios? →→ Reining in Lack of Investor Discipline: The Ulysses Strategy →→ Capital Markets Monthly →→ Dividends instead of low interest rates →→ Behavioral Finance – Two Minds at work →→ Behavioral Finance and the Post-Retirement Crisis →→ Is easy monetary policy fuelling new economic imbalances and credit bubbles? All our publications, analysis and studies can be found on the following webpage: http://www.allianzglobalinvestors.com Investing involves risk. The value of an investment and the income from it will fluctuate and investors may not get back the principal invested. Past performance is not indicative of future performance. This is a marketing communication. It is for informational purposes only. This material does not constitute investment advice or a recommendation to buy, sell or hold any security and shall not be deemed an offer to sell or a solicitation of an offer to buy any security. The views and opinions expressed herein, which are subject to change without notice, are those of the issuer or its affiliated companies at the time of publication. Certain data used are derived from various sources believed to be reliable, but the accuracy or completeness of the data is not guaranteed and no liability is assumed for any direct or consequential losses arising from their use. The duplication, publication, extraction or transmission of the contents, irrespective of the form, is not permitted. This material has not been reviewed by any regulatory authorities. In mainland China, it is used only as supporting material to the offshore investment products offered by commercial banks under the Qualified Domestic Institutional Investors scheme pursuant to applicable rules and regulations. This material is being distributed by the following Allianz Global Investors companies: Allianz Global Investors U.S. LLC, an investment adviser registered with the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC); Allianz Global Investors GmbH, an investment company in Germany, authorized by the German Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (BaFin); Allianz Global Investors Asia Pacific Ltd., licensed by the Hong Kong Securities and Futures Commission; Allianz Global Investors Singapore Ltd., regulated by the Monetary Authority of Singapore [Company Registration No. 199907169Z]; and Allianz Global Investors Japan Co., Ltd., registered in Japan as a Financial Instruments Business Operator; Allianz Global Investors Korea Ltd., licensed by the Korea Financial Services Commission; and Allianz Global Investors Taiwan Ltd., licensed by Financial Supervisory Commission in Taiwan.