benefits and costs of integrated financial services providers
Transcription
benefits and costs of integrated financial services providers
EU‐CHINA BMT WORKING PAPER SERIES No.006 BENEFITS AND COSTS OF INTEGRATED FINANCIAL SERVICES PROVIDERS (IFSP) ‐ STATE‐OF‐THE‐ART IN RESEARCH Prof. Dr. Horst Loechel Frankfurt School of Finance & Management Shanghai International Banking and Finance Institute 17F/D, World Plaza, 855 Pudong South Rd., Shanghai 200120, P. R. China [email protected] Dr. Heike Brost Frankfurt School of Finance & Management Sonnemannstrasse 9‐11, D‐60314 Frankfurt am Main, Germany h.brost@frankfurt‐school.de Helena Xiang Li (Corresponding author) Frankfurt School of Finance & Management Sonnemannstrasse 9‐11, D‐60314 Frankfurt am Main, Germany h.x.li@frankfurt‐school.de Abstract This paper aims to review the theoretical findings and empirical evidence of the benefits and costs of integrated financial services providers (IFSP) and draw inferences of developing IFSP in emerging markets with special consideration on China. The overall results can not conclude the superiority of IFSP or of segregated financial institutions. In opposite, the evaluation of the integration or segregation of financial institutions should always be embedded in the regulatory and managerial context. However, we could draw some implications that developing IFSP is of special relevance for emerging countries: The existing dominance of banking institutions in emerging national economies with the co-existence of underdeveloped capital markets can be leveraged for capital market innovation if lending, underwriting and brokerage services are available under one roof for the current client base. Cross-selling of banking and insurance products through bancassurance can better serve retail clients with comprehensive advisory for sophisticated life-time financial planning and can better complement the undeveloped social security system in emerging countries. Relationship banking and bank monitoring can better solve the problem of information asymmetry in emerging markets with lower transparency, underdeveloped corporate governance standard and weaker contract enforcement mechanism. As China is almost the unique country in the world still with commercial bank law favoring segregated financial system and the current ongoing deregulation process on the incremental trial basis is progressing, understanding the benefits and costs of IFSP can be of special importance as the next cornerstone for China’s banking reform. Keywords: Integrated financial services provider; universal banking; bancassurance; emerging countries; China JEL classification: G20, G21, G28 2 Introduction The discussion about the advantages and drawbacks of an integrated approach of financial institutions has a long history of over eighty years. This fundamental financial system design question was intensively debated already in the 1930s when the enforcement of the GlassSteagall Act 1933 in the USA finally declared the overhand of a segregated banking system strictly prohibiting commercial banks from the involvement in investment banking business. However, this segregated system was criticized by academics since its birth. Especially the costs of forgone advantages from economies of scale and economies of scope speak strongly against the separation of different service lines in the financial service industry. Global competition and the financial market deregulation trend accelerated the erosion of the segregated banking system in recent years and the implementation of Gramm-Leach-Bliley Financial Services Modernization Act in 1999 finalized the end of the era of segregated banking system in the USA. The global trend towards IFSP was already observed in the early 90s by Ferrara (1990). He argues the shrinking information and transaction costs realized through modern communication technology makes securitization more important as substitute for traditional bank credit function and he emphasizes the efficiency gains from more market competition and risk reduction through diversification in a financial system with IFSPs. The more developed capital market a country has, the greater are clients’ needs for more sophisticated and individualized financial products. A money market fund could for example substitute bank deposit. A bank with solely traditional deposit taking and lending functions can hardly survive in the fierce global competition on the financial markets with increasing complicity of product innovation and deepening capital securitization. In light of the current credit crisis, the discussion of benefits and costs of IFSP became even pronounced. The bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers with over 150 years of history, and the sale of leading investment banks Bear Stearns to JP Morgan Chase, Merrill Lynch to Bank of America raised the question about the end of era of the pure style investment banking. The left two leading investment banks Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs both turned to be bank holding companies with the allowance to enter into commercial banking business of deposit taking to enlarge funding basis. Kevin (2008) from American Banker renews the debate on universal banking and argues that more diversity in the business mix can provide financial institutions more consistency of funding and stability, giving universal banks Citi Group, Bank of America and JPMorgan Chase as examples. The risk diversification effect of IFSP turned out to be the decisive competitive advantage for the survival of financial institutions in times of system shock. The lessons learned regarding the development of IFSP in industrialized countries are especially valuable for financial system design in transition countries. Comparing the cost of financing in the second industrial revolution in the United States and Germany between 1870 to 1913, Calomiris (1995) concludes that the universal banking system contributed the industrial development in Germany by offering lower financing costs for large-scale production and new products and technologies due to lower information and control costs with the universal bank system in Germany. He underlines the importance of the development of IFSP for contemporary emerging countries: “Developing countries designing financial systems should take a lesson from U.S. financial history and avoid a costly, lengthy detour through financial fragmentation.” 3 As one of the largest emerging countries in the world, China made great effort and success in the last thirty years of reform in transforming a mono banking system in a plan economy to a competitive modern banking system in pace with the development of the socialistic market economy (Loechel, Zhao, 2006). A current striking fact of banking regulation and supervision in China is however the lag of its Banking Act with strict separation of banking from securities and insurance services behind the global deregulation trend and market development. In a survey of banking regulation in 107 countries over the world done by Barth, Caprio and Levine (2001), China receives the highest score in overall banking activities and ownership restrictiveness. Claessens and Klingebiel (2001) note China is the only country with segregated financial system among 51 industrial and emerging countries surveyed by the Institute of International bankers in 1998. In a latter Global Survey 2007 of Institute of International Bankers about banking regulation in 51 developed and developing countries, China is the only country with strict prohibition of banks’ engagement in securities, insurance, real estate and industrial firms. Deregulation and building up a financial system based on IFSPs could be the next cornerstone of the banking reform in China. In this context, this paper reviews relevant theoretical findings and empirical evidence to date regarding benefits and costs of IFSP and draws implications for future financial system design in emerging countries with China in focus. Section 1 gives definition of IFSP. Section 2 and section 3 discuss the benefits and costs of IFSP respectively. Section 4 draws implications of the relevance and limitations of IFSP for emerging countries, especially for China. Section 5 provides conclusions and outlook. Section 1: Definition An IFSP is defined as a financial institution which provides a wide range of services including mixtures of consumer banking, commercial banking, investment banking, asset management, insurance services or any other kind of financial services. Compared to a universal bank which combines commercial and investment banking businesses, an IFSP extends the service to other finance-related business lines, especially insurance services. IFSP can be performed in different combinations like commercial banking with investment banking, bancassurance, and financial conglomerate either through direct participation or subsidiaries. According to EU Financial Conglomerate Directive 2002, an IFSP can be structured through four different organisation forms: the integrated model with all services provided within one entity; the parent-subsidiary model; the holding company model and the horizontal group model through contracts of association instead of through direct or indirect capital links. To protect the interest of insured parties, EU Life Assurance Directive and Non-Life Insurance Directive regulate that insurance business can only be undertaken by separate legal entities. Saunders and Walter (1994) summarize the four organisation types of universal bank (see also Biswas, Loechel, 2001): 4 When a universal bank extends its business to insurance, the question arises how to integrate the insurance business into conventional banking business. Are banking managers capable to manage risks in insurance business of total different kind such as the risk of accrual estimation? Saunders and Walter (1996) underline the following similarities of insurance with banking: mortality analysis in insurance is comparable with loan default rate analysis in lending; both insurance asset return and loan return depend on interest rate development; both face similar adverse selection and moral hazard problems; reinsurance and sale of loan portfolio have similar pattern of risk transfer; synergies can be gained through joint management for exposure of liquidity risk. Sharing the distribution channel of banks to crosssell insurance products proves to be the successful model of bancassurance in Western Europe. Section 2: Benefits 5 2.1. Economies of scale and scope Economies of scale and scope are regarded as the strongest argument for the integrated banking model among the advocates of IFSP and are driving forces for bank merges. Economies from scale effect and enhanced scope can be achieved both from revenue enhancement and costs reduction. On the revenue side, economies of scope can be realized through “cross-selling”. IFSP benefits from the insider information gained in the previous client relationship and through the individual client life-cycle for cross-sell new products. Retail banking clients have the opportunity to choose products from a basket of products provided by the same bank to meet their individual financial needs. While specialized investment bank will loss underwriting clients in time of “cold” equity market, IFSP can offer its corporate client a suited loan product to finance investment projects. Underwriting of corporate bonds in foreign currency can be bundled with currency swaps to better align the capital market sentiment to corporate financing needs. On the costs side, reduced information and transaction costs by sharing monitoring activity based on the same client information, the usage of the same information technology platform and the spread of managerial overhead costs provide IFSP advantages of economies of scale. A lender and a broker for example may face the same market interest risk for the existing loan portfolio and for corporate bonds trading. The consolidated management of overall market risk, liquidity risk, counterparty risk and operational risk can generate synergies for cost savings. Sharing the same brand for multiple products can leverage the existing reputation to promote new products and realize marketing savings. Information gained from one-time client transaction is valuable in the context of relationship banking. For example, an investment banking affiliate can use client information generated from the lending relationship and save information gathering costs for underwriting due-diligence. A bank with established money management facility can use the capacity to set up mutual funds management affiliates for retail customers. For bank clients, cost savings can be achieved through reduced search and contract costs as well as switching costs. Geographic scope of an international bank can be an extra source of revenue enhancing by offering clients global solution of custody, clearance and cash management, the so-called “network economies” (Walter (2003)). In contrast to the theoretical possibilities of scale and scope economies, the empirical evidence shows economies of scale and scope only exist for small- and middle-sized financial institutions, whereas the diseconomies of scale and scope dominate in large institutions due to inefficient management for complex large scale of business. Based on Walter (2003), economies of scale are only empirically proven for small financial institution with assets below USD 100 million. Rime and Stiroh (2003) examine the scale and scope economies of 289 Swiss universal banks from 1996 to 1999 and find evidence of scale economies for small to middle-sized banks. Clark (1996) finds scale economies in the sense of both production and economic efficiency can not be achieved if a bank’s total asset expands over USD 2 billion. There is some evidence that European universal banks can better channel economies of scale and scope. Vennet (1998) analyzes 2,375 banks covering the period of 1995 to 1996 from 17 countries in the European Union where financial conglomerate is legally allowed through EU Second Banking Directive (1989). He finds evidence that financial conglomerates are more 6 cost efficient in non-traditional banking activities than specialized banks, whereas the cost efficiency of the two bank types differs not much in traditional intermediation activities. Compared to specialized banks, universal banks have superior profit efficiency related to comparative information advantage. Using bank data of 850 banks from France, Germany, Italy and Spain in 1988, Altunbas and Molyneux (1996) document the existence of economies of scale in European banking markets and economies of scope in Germany. A special form of IFSP with the combination of banking and insurance is bancassurance, either through horizontal merger, through joint-venture or through strategic alliance and cross-selling agreements. The original idea is to leverage banks’ branch and other distribution channels to cross-sell insurance products to generate commission income and diversify revenues, providing motorcycle insurance for lenders of motorcycle loan for example. This concept meets clients’ needs for convenience buy and for comprehensive advisory for sophisticated life-cycle finance planning. The established relationship between life-time finance advisors and clients especially generated from life insurance products can help banks boost the potential of cross-selling based on gained clients information, for example, establishment of the client relationship through granting education loan in early years and promotion of child endowment account for the “event” of clients’ child’s birth in later years of client’s life cycle. The drawback of bancassurance is that some of the life insurance product could substitute some depositary products and the product knowledge of banking advisor especially for property/casualty insurance products is limited. Several studies confirm empirically the potential of economies of scope and risk reduction through the combination of banking and insurance. Chen, Li, Moshirian and Tan (2006) analyze 213 bancassurance mergers in Europe from 1986 to 2004 and conclude the systematic risk of acquirers falls while the short-term abnormal return is negative for bidders. Fields, Fraser and Kolari (2007) examine 129 bancassurance merges among U.S. and non-U.S. companies from 1997 to 2002 and prove small positive bidder return after announcement, whereas the merger does not alter the risk profile of acquiring firms. Chen, Li, Liao, Moshirian and Szablocs (2008) provide a comprehensive study of 71 bancassurance companies in 28 developed and developing countries for the period between 1999 and 2003. Their finding confirms the risk reduction through diversification and cost savings in large operations. Okeahalam (2008) finds retail bancassurance products are six percent cheaper than the sum of stand-alone products in South Africa indicating cost savings through economies of scale and scope passed through to customers. However, large scale economy goes hand in hand with increased bank size and lower competition on the market. The abuse of oligopolistic market power can reduce the scale economy for the social welfare through increased interest margin and less competition on the market can lead to reluctance of efficiency improvement. This drawback is discussed in detail below in section 3.4. 2.2. Risk diversification and contribution to financial market stability Another significant benefit of IFSP is the risk reduction due to low correlation of revenues from different business lines and reduced bankruptcy risk which leads to higher credit rating and lower refinancing costs. From the macroeconomic perspective, risk reduction of universal banks also promotes the stability of the entire financial system due to reduced counterparty risk in inter-bank markets and lower probability of bank-run. In an IFSP, losses from one business line, let’s say, from investment banking which is inherent more volatile to market fluctuations, can be first absorbed by profits generated in lending business, instead that the whole bank goes bankruptcy which affects the stability of the whole financial system due to 7 the interlinks in the banking industry. The current financial crisis and the relative stability of banks comprising both commercial banking and investment banking business like Citi Group and Bank of America provided evidence of risk reduction through the integration of different service lines. The World Economic Outlook October 2008 issued by International Monetary Fund confirms empirically the pro-cyclicality of leverage of investment banking and commercial banking in a more arm’s-length financial system, which leads to higher vulnerability to system risk in economic downturns or recessions. This is in line with the finding that the overall impact of the financial turmoil is greater in the United States than in Europe where the universal banking system dominates. Empirically, the risk reduction in universal banking can be proven through correlation analysis between income from banking and non-banking businesses, Nurullah and Staikouras (2008) summarize the correlation analyses in previous studies as follows: As shown in the table above, the returns from banking and non-banking activities are in general negative correlated (negative sign in the brackets). The combination of banking with life insurance has the greatest potential to reduce the return volatility due to the significant negative correlation of returns. Rich and Walter (1993) also find slightly negative correlation between net interest income from loans and income from commissions among Swiss universal banks indicating risk reduction potential of combining lending and underwriting. The study on risk and return impact of banks’ expansion in non-banking businesses remains another research interest on IFSP. Boyd and Graham (1986) examine the risk feature of 64 largest bank holding companies in the United States from 1971 to 1983 and find no altering of the risk pattern after the expansion in non-banking activities. Boyd and Graham (1988) further analyze the risk and profitability effects of allowing bank holding companies to merge with other financial firms based on simulated mergers using dataset of 249 publicly traded banks and non-bank firms from the period of 1971 to 1984. Their study show the expansion in securities or real estate sector increases the risk of failure of bank holding companies whereas the combination with life insurance companies decreases the volatility of return and achieves risk diversification. Their findings could provide implications for the regulatory setting of allowed activities of IFSP. Chong, Liu and Altunbas (1999) show the repeal of segregated financial system through the Financial System Reform Act in 1992 and the development of universal banking in Japan increased Japanese financial institutions’ exposure to market risk and lowered the interest rate exposure. Allen and Jagtiani (2000) find combining banking with securities and insurance activities reduces the overall risk. Nurullah and Staikouras (2008) 8 study empirically the impact of European banks’ diversification into life, non-life insurance underwriting and insurance broking on risk and profitability. They conclude the return of enter into life underwriting and insurance broking increases significantly, whereas banks’ risk with combination with life and non-life insurance underwriting also increases. Claessens (2002) further emphasizes the increase of fee-income in IFSP can compensate the decline of interest income with the trend of dis-intermediation when firms tend to raise funds more directly from the capital market. This revenue diversification in IFSP establishes the revenue resources and prevents banks from riskier lending. Moreover, the expansion of geographic scope of banks can contribute to overall risk reduction. Covering data from 38 international banks from eight industrialized countries during 1995 and 2004, the study of Garcia-Herrero and Vazquez (2007) reveals foreign subsidiaries especially in emerging countries where the business cycle is not so synchronized with that of home countries contribute to enhanced risk-adjusted return of the whole banking Group. Another question regarding IFSP and banks’ risk taking is how the setting of IFSP is subject to risk enhancing or risk reduction and thus should draw special attention by regulators. Using stylized models, John, John and Saunders (1994) prove banks’ equity holding in firms with veto rights over borrowing firms’ investment policy increases the investment efficiency but at the same time increases the risk of banks’ asset. Banks’ equity holding with firm controlled investment can however increase investment efficiency and reduce the risk of banks’ portfolio. Regulators should take into account the impact of different combination patterns of permitted banking services on risks and incentives of bank and corporate. There are some studies on the relationship of IFSP with the financial crises in past years. Wilmarth (2005) asks the role of universal banks in the U.S. boom-and-bust cycle of 1921 to 1933. He argues universal banks fueled oil in the economic expansion between 1924 and 1929 through loan to securities, securities investment, public offerings of securities, real estate mortgages and consumer credit. The analysis of the relationship between banking system architecture and banking crisis in IMF’s World Economic Outlook October 2008 provides the contradictory conclusion: one lesson learned from financial distresses in 17 advanced economies over the last 30 years is “economies with financial systems dominated by morearm’s-length transactions, as opposed to traditional relationship-based intermediation, tend to exhibit higher procyclical leverage”, which increases the finance system fragility. In some countries, the limitation of the functional scope is the result from regulatory restrictions. Based on their survey data on bank regulations of 142 countries, Barth, Caprio and Levine (2008) find that regulatory restrictions increase the possibility of banking crisis. They explain the result with the argument that diversification reduces the fragility of banks to shocks. The regulatory setting for or against the integrated banking model should therefore always be put in the context of maintaining system stability and enhancing the system ability to prevent and encounter system shocks. 2.3. Information advantage and relationship banking The financial service industry is characterized with higher information and transaction costs. Banks as delegated monitors (Diamond (1984)) for information gathering and monitoring have inherent advantage over capital markets. Sharing client information for different services in a universal bank can significantly reduce the costs of information collection and enhance information usage. The life-time relationship induces banks to collect inside information even with higher information gathering costs which financial institutions in a single transaction 9 relationship are hardly ready to bear. More important, information gained from one business line, credit history, for example, can give important indication for other businesses, like debt issuing. Using this information, banks can explore the cross-selling potential to meet clients’ individual needs at lower costs. The “house bank” principle furthermore adds value over the whole client life cycle. In relationship banking, banks collect more private information, the loan contracts are more flexible and in favor of long-term projects and moral hazard problems are less predominant. Boot (2000) emphasizes long-term relationship can induce the debtor to disclose more private information not available to the financial market and the bank to invest more in information gathering. The contracts in relationship banking tend to have more flexible feature and are easier for renegotiation than other capital markets instruments like corporate bonds. Bank monitoring of collateral reduces the problem of moral hazard. The reduced information asymmetry can facilitate inter-temporal smoothing in favor of the realization of long-term projects. As potential drawbacks, he highlights the soft-budget problem if the bank is lack of the enforcement power and the hold-up problem if the bank misuses its informational monopoly and negotiation power. Allen and Gale (1999) prove in their model the importance to maintain long-term relationship in the enforcement of implicit contracts between banks and investors with high ex-ante cost. Cabral and Santos (2001) prove in a stylized way that increased points of contracts in a repeated relationship can improve contract efficiency in a one-sided or two-sided moral hazard context even in the absence of efficiency of information gathering. Burghof (1999) analyzes the advantage of banking lending in gathering private information by examining actual credit files of six medium-sized corporate customer of a major German universal bank. He documents on average 94% of information gathered in the credit files are private information not available on the security market and creditors actively use interaction with bank for signaling and bonding in cases of turnaround or bankruptcy. He confirms the importance of banks as delegated monitors in firm lending. Based on data of 1,302 Japanese domestic bond issuance for the period of 1994 to 1999, Yasuda (2007) provides evidence that lending relationship positively affects firms’ underwriter choice and this relationship especially in a multiple relationship context benefits firms with significant underwriting fee discount. The relationship banking benefits firms with smoothed loan lending over the business cycle and is especially crucial in times of firms’ financial distress. Using UK syndicated loan data from 1996 to 2005, Steffen (2008) reveals remaining lending relationship with banks can help firms to smooth loan lending rates over the business cycle. Ramírez (1999) also finds the sharp decrease of bank-firm affiliation after the enactment of the Glass-Steagall-Act increased the cash-flow sensitivity of former bank-affiliated companies for investment and demonstrates relationship banking in a universal banking context can facilitate firms to encounter financial constrains. Hoshi, Kashyap and Scharfstein (1990) provide evidence that financially distressed firms with close relationship with “main bank” in Japan invest and sell more compared to firms not in such relationship. They argue relationship banking can avoid the free-rider problem in renegotiation of financial claims and reduce information asymmetry about firms’ investment prospects in times of financial distress. Elsas and Krahnen (2004) analyze the German setting of relationship banking (Hausbank relationship) and show evidence the Hausbank relationship is beneficial for small firms as credit insurance in times of workouts and financial distress. 10 Herrera and Minetti (2007) focus on the role of relationship banking in fostering firms’ technological innovation. Based on data of over 4,000 Italian manufacturing firms for the period of 1998 to 2000 and their credit relationship, they uncover the main banks help to channel funds for the introduction and acquisition of new technologies. Relationship banking can also be of interest for retail clients. Analyzing the allocation data of 72 IPO underwritten by German universal banks from 1997 to 2004, Puri and Rocholl (2008) reveal retail customers of banks acting both as deposit taker and lead underwriter can benefit from relationship banking by being better informed and encouraged to subscribe underpriced IPO securities issued by the same bank. They also uncover banks benefit from this relationship for cross-selling brokerage service and retail customer loans. 2.4. More efficient internal capital market The decision, if certain financial service line should be integrated in one financial Group or be executed arms-length through external market, depends on the efficiency comparison of internal versus external capital markets. Current financial crisis demonstrates the importance of internal capital market especially for liquidity management in case of distortion of external financing on the inter-bank markets. The drawback is however that cross-subsidization could decrease the incentives of profitable business lines or lead to over-investment in low NPV projects. Koeppl and MacGee (2005) provide valuable evidence that cross-subsidization of a broad bank can achieve higher levels of aggregate investment, higher output and less fluctuation in the presence of liquidity and asset shocks compared to regional bank linked with interbank markets. In general, the incentive system for internal valuation of business lines should be based on the market discipline. Setting up internal rules of reward and penalty for intra-Group transactions remains the core task of setting up proper incentive mechanism in IFSP. 2.5. Bank monitoring and promotion of firm performance Possessing internal information about the lenders in relationship banking, banks can better judge a firm’s financial situation and the prospect of its long-term investment. Banks can leverage their industrial expertise to advise bank clients’ investment decisions. In a universal bank model with banks’ equity holding, it’s of banks’ own interest to foster firms’ growth and provide finance insurance in times of restructuring and distress. Benston (1994) emphasizes the transaction costs of takeovers and mergers in case of firm restructuring are higher in a stock market system than in a universal bank. He further posits bank’s holding of both debt and equity in a firm can facilitate the firm to find the best debtequity mix and can give firms better finance support in time of distress. 2.6. Bank loan in small and middle sized enterprises (SME) financing The impact of the universality of banks on SME financing is not obvious. On the one hand, reduced information asymmetry and monitoring costs and enlarged product portfolio can better serve the special needs of SME which hardly have entrance to capital markets for financing, since SME are less subject to mandatory disclosure, weakly monitored by rating agencies and draw less attention on the capital market. On the other hand, increased bank size alongside with enlarged scale and scope facilitates the tendency of centralized credit rationing which speaks against the support of financing SME. 11 Peterson and Rajan (1994) reveal the lending pattern of firms in the United States and show the smallest firms more relay on debt financing from concentrated sources of one lender and prove empirically that closer ties with banks can increase the availability of funding due to reduced information asymmetry and agency costs. They also uncover firms with lending relationship with multiple banks are charged with higher interest rate. Ely and Robinson (2004) however find no significant difference of the proportion of small business portion at commercial banks with or without securities affiliates. Montoriol-Garriga (2008) investigates the impact of domestic bank merges in Spain between 1996 and 2005 on small business lending and observes a higher possibility of termination of the lending relationship with the consolidated bank for smallest borrowers. However, there is a significant reduction in loan interest rate to smallest and youngest borrowers which are capable to continue the lending relationship after the merger. She accounts this positive effect to efficiency gains from economies of scale and scope as well as risk diversification after the merger. How to facilitate the credit entrance of SME in a financial system in line with the IFSP model should be well considered by regulators. Section 3: Costs 3.1. Conflicts of interest The problem of conflicts of interest remains the loudest voice against the development of IFSP and has been intensively discussed in the context of financial system re-design especially in the United States for the introduction of segregated financial system in 1933 and the deregulation in 1999. Conflicts of interest can arise in different ways: Banks could use the private information to remove loans with lower quality from the balance sheet by converting the loans into public securities (conflict of interest); Banks could tie loan terms with firms’ willingness to mandate the bank with underwriting business (tying) etc. Conflicts of interest arising in IFSP can be classified according different roles of IFSP: 3.1.1. Lender and underwriter A large body of literature investigates conflicts of interest in a universal bank providing both lending and underwriting services. The core question lies in whether universal banks use their private information of loan clients to sell “lemons” to uninformed investors by underwriting loans of lower quality and removing them from their own balance sheet to the capital market. Another focus is on banks’ tie-in sales such as setting the engagement as security underwriting advisor as pre-condition for lending or granting investor loan with below-market interest rate to purchase securities underwritten by affiliated unit. 12 Theoretically, the combination of lending and underwriting brings cost savings in information gathering. Puri (1999) proves with a stylized model that the private information gained by commercial banks through the prior claim relationship can help banks better certify the true value of the firm for the underwriting. This link holds especially when the costs of information gathering are high. Empirically, evidence of conflict of interest for banks acting both as lender and underwriter is rare. In contrast, the information advantage gained from the lending relationship for underwriting securities is predominant. An early study of Puri (1996) analyzing the ex-ante yield of underwritten securities by commercial banks and investment banks of pre-Glass-Steagall period has shown that investors are willing to pay more (lower ex-ante yield) for securities underwritten by commercial banks as the reward of the certification role of banks with private information generated from the loan making and monitoring activities. This effect is more salient for junior and information sensitive securities. Similarly to Puri’s study, Hebb and Fraser (2002) document a lower yield for securities underwritten by commercial banks based on data from 1987 to 1997 after the revoke of law separating commercial and investment banking in Canada in 1987 and contradict the conflict of interest hypothesis. Compared to the U.S. experience, Kang and Liu (2007) examine corporate bonds issues in Japan between 1995 and 1997 after the issuance of Financial System Reform Act (1993) which repealed the separation of commercial banking from investment activities. They find bank-underwritten bonds carry higher yields thus are lower priced compared to bonds underwritten by investment houses. The underpricing is more pronounced for issuer with lower credit rating or the bank serves as main bank. Their explanation is the lending power of commercial banks presses the issuing price in order to attract investors. They call for caution of commercial banks’ certification role in underwriting especially for emerging countries where the heavy reliance of corporate on banks could strengthen banks’ power and conflicts of interest between lender and underwriter could be intensified. Ber, Yafeh and Yosha (2001) analyze the post-issue performance of 128 Israeli IPOs underwritten by universal banks also acting as creditor and fund manager and find evidence of significant post-issue superior accounting performance of IPOs underwritten by bank affiliates with lending relationship in the same year of the IPO. Their results can be interpreted as evidence of the information advantage gained by a bank underwriter through the lending relationship. However, the performance of IPOs purchased by the investment fund affiliates of the underwriting bank exhibits both low first day and first year performance which indicates potential conflict of interest in affiliated fund management at the cost of fund investors. Drucker and Puri (2005) further reveal the majority of firms engaged in concurrent lending and underwriting with the same bank are highly leveraged and noninvestment-grade rated firms and argue the information advantage gained from the lending relationship reduces the underwriting fee significantly especially for noninvestment-graded firms. Krishnan (2007) examines the behavior of U.S. banks between 1990 and 2003 after firms’ debt issuance and demonstrates that banks do not punish loan clients with less credit and higher spread if the client did not give the bank underwriting mandate as supposed in “tying hypothesis”. Instead, banks use information gathered in the underwriting process to avoid loan approval to clients with lower quality. Thus, access to both lending and underwriting leads to lower financing costs and better loan allocation and the argument of conflict of 13 interest is in this case contradicted. Laux and Walz (2007) confirm Krishnan’s results in their modeling and emphasize universal banking tend to underwrite less innovative firms while specialized investment banks more possibly serve innovative start-up underwriters or seasoned equity offerings of growth firms. Based on the examination of 270 IPOs of German firms between 1997 and 1999, Klein and Zoeller (2003) observe the long-term performance of IPOs underwritten by universal banks does not distinguish much from those underwritten by specialized investment banks. They therefore contradict the presumption of universal banks’ underwriting of lower quality securities. 3.1.2. Lender and equity holder With bankers sitting on the board, firms can improve the information flow with its creditors and establish a reliable credit relationship especially valuable for long-term financing and in times of financial distress and restructuring. Having bankers as board members, firms can benefit from the bank’s certification role indicating that the firm has less possibility of default. Banks’ industrial expertise and know-how in financing and restructuring can provide firms valuable advices. In an IFSP with merchant banking, banks with equity holding directly or through trust affiliates or with proxy rights may influence corporate decision through lending power or mandates sitting in boards of non-financial companies. This may impose the conflict between shareholder and creditor in protecting shareholders’ interest due to different payoff structure of debt and equity, such as banks’ approval of lending with below-market rates in favor of the shareholder role or neglecting riskier investment project with positive net present value to protect creditor’s interest Kroszner and Strahan (2001) observe that one third of large U.S. firms have a banker on board and regard this as indication that the benefits of banks’ monitoring role outweigh the costs of conflict of interest. Santos and Rumble (2006) also document that the largest 100 American banks control on average 10% of the voting rights of S&P 500 firms through their trust business based on data at the end of 2000. In Germany with traditional equity holding of universal banks, Esen (2001) however observes the shrinking trend of German banks’ shares in industrial companies and emphasizes the international competition pressure forces German universal banks to use the capital more flexibly which changes the shareholding pattern of universal banks. 3.1.3. Lender and asset manager The sharing of information gained from the lending business can give the in-house asset manager indication for the quality of issued securities to generate superior return to funds managed by the same house. Massa and Rehman (2008) provide valuable insight on the benefits of the combination of lending and asset management for IFSP on the costs of uninformed investors. They uncover that mutual funds tend to increase stakes in firms which borrowed from the affiliated banks in the prior period and these stocks outperform stakes without borrowing from the affiliations. They suspect financial conglomerate makes use of informal information flows such as personal acquaintances to generate superior returns. 14 3.1.4. Underwriter and sales broker/researcher Conflict of interest can occur if sell-side research analysts issue optimistic biased broker report for securities underwritten by the affiliate underwriting unit to promote issuance of the same house. Lehar and Randl (2003) examine the behavior of affiliated analysts in equity research department of nine German universal banks between 1994 and 2001. They find evidence that affiliated analysts behave strategically by issuing optimistic forecasts when the consensus forecast underestimates actual earnings and by hiding among non-affiliated analysts when the consensus is overoptimistic. Thus, affiliated analysts can cultivate firm-bank relationship by issuing optimistic forecasts and improve forecast accuracy using superior information advantage. Their study proves empirically the existence of conflict of interest in IFSP with both underwriting and sales broking facilities. Based on sell-side analyst recommendations during 1994 and 2000, Ljungqvist, Marston, Starks, Wei and Yan (2007) also document the optimistic bias in recommendations issued by analysts with established investment banking relationship with covered firms and when the affiliated banks also provide brokerage services. This conflict of interest can be however limited with the presence of institutional ownership of covered firms since analysts must balance the pressure from investment banking and brokerage unit with their reputation among institutional investors linked with career concerns. 3.1.5. Underwriter and asset manager Concerns arise regarding conflict of interest in IFSP with both underwriting and asset management facilities, whether asset managers are put in pressure to purchase securities brought public by the underwriting affiliate of the same house or to buy shares to support price of cold IPOs of the bank’s clients. Allocating hot IPOs to affiliated funds could in turn boost the fund’s performance and attract more money flow to the bank. Johnson and Marietta-Westberg (2005) analyze 2,412 U.S. IPOs between 1993 to 1999 and provide evidence that asset manager can utilize superior information gained by underwriting affiliates in IPO to generate abnormal returns, while non-underwriter asset manager trades mostly short-term momentum. In return, holding big portion of stocks by IPO underwriter’s asset management unit increases the probability to gain the SEO underwriting business significantly. Ritter and Zhang (2007) examine the allocation of 2,257 U.S. IPOs to mutual funds affiliates from 1990 to 2001 and find no significant evidence of favored allocation of IPOs to affiliated mutual funds. Only in the internet bubble between 1999 and 2000, investment banks preferentially allocated underpriced IPOs to affiliated mutual funds to generate superior return. 3.1.6. Asset manager and sales broker/researcher Conflict of interest can arise with “salesman’s stake” if the asset manager promotes the highmargin house products. Asset manager may also induce frequent trades conducted by the affiliated sales brokers to generate more commission fees on the cost of retail clients. As a prominent case for conflicts of interests in multidivisional bank, Walter (2006) gives the relationship between Citi Group and WorldCom as an example. Citi Group served 15 simultaneously as equity analyst, strategic and finance advisor, lender, underwriter, pension fund advisor, trader for executive stock options, stock holder and stock trader for WorldCom. Conflicts of interest of Citi Group played a non-negligible role in the scandal of WorldCom. As measures to control such conflict of interest, Walter (2006) suggests three channels: regulation, civil litigation and market discipline. Prudential regulation of insider trading and the enhancement of market transparency are best measures to encounter conflict of interest. On the one hand, the establishment of organizational constraints in law by requirement of conduction of conflicting business lines through segregated subsidiaries or installation of firewalls between conflicting service lines can provide necessary prevention of the abuse of information advantages and moral hazard problems in IFSP. On the other hand, strengthening market discipline, public supervision and shareholder self-protection can supplement regulation and litigation. At the same time, competitive market pressure and reputation consideration can also induce IFSP to set up safeguards and structures to avoid conflicts of interest. Mehran and Stulz (2007) also emphasize the combination of market mechanism such as pricing discount due to awareness of conflict of interest, analysts and funds reputation in ranking, market competition along with regulation and litigation can mitigate the adverse impact of conflicts of interest in IFSP. 3.2. Spill-over effect The establishment of the segregation of commercial banking and investment banking is borne in the banking crisis in the United States in 1930s when massive losses from security affiliates affected the commercial banking arm. How to prevent the spill-over effect of riskier security trading business to the safety of commercial deposit taking remains the main concern of opponents of the universal banking system. Spill-over effect can also be reputation-related if a scandal from one division damages the overall-brand and causes loss of customers for other sound business lines. Since confidence is crucial in the financial services industry, the spillover effect of reputation damage can overweight the marketing savings from sharing one brand. Due to the large size of financial institutions to generate economies of scale and scope in a system with IFSP, how to avoid the negative spill-over effect from the failure of one business arm in one institution to the total financial system remains a crucial task for regulators in a financial architecture with integrated models. 3.3. Moral hazard and impact on the financial safety-net The aim of central banks as lender-of-last-resort and the deposit insurance system is to prevent the chain-effect of bank runs caused by lost confidence of depositors. The interlink of different business lines in financial conglomerate reduces the transparency of the cause for bank failure and can induce moral hazard of bank managers for more risk taking. Moreover, increased size of universal banks can enhance the moral hazard problem by increased bail-out possibility due to too-big-to-fail-guarantee. Boyd (1999) posits the allowance of universal banking can expand the government induced moral hazard problem by the existence of financial safety net like deposit insurance system to other sectors of the economy. In a financial system with permission of IFSP, how to restrict the shift of risks from securities and insurance businesses to deposit taking remains crucial. 3.4. Concentration and market power Another concern about IFSP is that the universality of banks can lead to concentration in the banking industry with market power of large banks and thus reduces market competition. 16 Fohlin (2000) investigates this issue by comparing the market concentration in pre-war Germany and the U.K. where universal banking system and separated banking system respectively dominated. She reveals the market concentration of Germany did not differ much from that in the U.K. Furthermore, she shows that the competitive pricing pattern of Germany behaved similarly as in the United States with separated banking system which indicates that the suggested interlink between universality and the distortion of market competition does not hold. Rich and Walter (1993) also show the market share of big banks in Germany with the dominance of universal banks has not changed much since 1960 while at the same time the universality of banks has extended. Thus the causality between market concentration and bank universality is contradicted. 3.5. Conglomerate discount The phenomenon of conglomerate discount (a share price discount for firms with more functional diversification compared to peers in the same industry) is well observed in nonfinancial industry. Laeven and Levine (2005) are among the first to investigate diversification discount of financial conglomerates with their study based on a sample of banks in 43 countries for a sample period from 1998 to 2002. Their results show that benefit gains from economies of scale and scope can not compensate the costs from agency problem between informed corporate insiders and small shareholders in financial conglomerate which are in result traded with a discount on the capital market compared to specialized financial institutions. Using U.S. dataset from 1985 to 2004, Schmid and Walter (2008) reveal comprehensively the existence of conglomerate discount in the financial services industry and conclude the total balance of functional diversification is value-destroying. However, with more differentiated analysis, they show the combination of commercial banking with insurance and the combination between commercial banking and investment banking produce significant premium. Some researchers try to reexamine the research design to solve the puzzle of the dominant finding of conglomerate discount and the positive stock price reaction of diversification merger. The question focuses if diversified firms are already traded with a discount prior to diversifying so that there is no causal relationship between diversification and diversification discount. Campa and Kedia (1999) raise the question of self-selection of diversified firms and prove that the conglomerate discount drops or sometimes disappears after the control of the endogenous problem in research methodology. Villalonga (2000) confirms their finding and show the diversification discount disappears or even turns to a premium when firms’ propensity to diversify is taken into account. However, financial institutions are not included in the both above studies and evidence engaging this research design problem for financial institutions is still vacant. 3.6.Negative impact on the development of capital markets A conventional opinion states that the preponderant role of large banks in a universal banking system hinders the development of capital markets. The evidence from Swiss capital market provided by Rich and Walter (1993) questions this assumption. They prove that the fixedincome security market and the equity holding by private households in Switzerland perform similar pattern as in the United States, whereas Switzerland together with Germany is regarded as banking markets with full range universality. 17 3.7. Negative impact on financial innovation As a common view, IFSP is embedded in a bank-based financial system like in Germany where financial innovation is sparse compared to in a market-based system like in the USA. Contradicting view argues the combination of different service lines promotes innovation of new products and distribution models. Kanatas and Qi (2003) posit the underwriting units of universal banks have less incentive to promote clients’ securities on the capital market compared to specialized investment banks, since lending products from the same house are available. They therefore argue the segregated financial system can better foster financial innovation. 3.8. Requirement for integrated supervision and comprehensive banking management In pace with the convergence of market segments in IFSP, the sectoral regulatory framework should be reconsidered. At least, the interaction of different sectoral supervisors should be strengthened. The practice of the European Union with the implementation of Financial Conglomerates Directive in December 2002 in the EU where the concept of IFSP was originated can provide a unique template for supervision of IFSP. Dierick (2004) highlights the five main risks involved in a financial conglomerate subject to special regulation: regulatory arbitrage through intra-group transactions, contagion due to spill-over to economic linked entities, moral hazard to financial safety net, the lack of transparency from group size and complexity, conflict of interest and abuse of economic power. The emphasis of financial conglomerate regulation should be put on group-wide capital adequacy and risk management, monitoring of intra-group transactions as well as coordination and information exchange between sectoral supervision authorities. The difficulties of supervising financial conglomerates can arise in various fields: The regulatory capital requirements for banking and insurance are different due to different risk pattern; A financial conglomerate with holding structure has the possibility to book the products and assets in the business line with the lower capital requirement – “regulatory arbitrage”; A holding company can raise external capital through debt issuance and infuse the capital raised as equity in subsidiaries as regulatory capital – the risk of “double leveraging” (Edwards (1998)). Freixas, Lóránth and Morrison (2005) investigate the optimal capital requirement for financial conglomerate through integrated model and through holding structure and prove in their stylized model that the integrated model induces more risk-taking incentive and should be subject to more regulatory capital. Cumming and Hirtle (2001) address the challenge of integrated risk management in financial conglomerate and highlight that financial conglomerates need longer time to determine the aggregated risk position in changes of market condition and may not able to react timely compared to specialized institutions. The complexity and speciality of financial conglomerates should draw special attention in the regulation and supervision. Section 4: Relevance and limitations of Developing IFSP in Emerging Countries 4.1. Relevance 18 To reconsider the benefits and costs of a financial system with IFSP is of high relevance in the reshaping process of international financial markets, not only because emerging countries are underway to transfer their banks from institutions with pure deposit taking and lending functions to modern competitive financial institutions with multiple services to better sustain economic growth, so the needs for theoretical foundation in IFSP for policy setting are large and urgent, but also because the finance crisis challenged the weaknesses of the existing IFSP models in developed countries which shows the simple copying of IFSP models from developed economies can not guarantee success for IFSP in emerging countries. There are some characteristics of emerging economies which make the development of IFSP to be of special relevance. In emerging countries, banking sector usually plays a crucial role in the financial system by channelling private savings to productive investment. The development of IFSP can make good use of the existing dominant role of banks as a solid basis to enhance the variety of financial services to sustain economic growth, stimulate the development of capital markets and promote the establishment of health and social insurance system. As the social wealth grows, it emerges to develop financial depth and sophistication of existing financial institutions. Especially in an environment of limited contract enforcement, immature bankruptcy procedure, lace of corporate governance, lower information transparency and less high quality disclosure like in most emerging countries, the role of IFSP as delegated monitors, promoters of capital markets and developer of insurance products can be essential. The contribution of IFSP to promoting economic growth and the development of financial markets can only be facilitated if the regulatory framework gives banks the allowance to be involved in various financial sectors, guides financial institutions to explore scale and scope economies and limits potential conflicting fields. In a comprehensive study based on data from 87 developed and developing countries between 1980 and 2004, Fernández, González and Suárez (2008) prove bank concentration with large bank size can foster economic growth in poor-quality of institutional environment. They explain their finding by stressing the governance function of bank monitoring in case of higher information asymmetry in countries with weaker market discipline. Based on a sample of Chinese listed firms from the Shanghai Stock Exchange and Shenzhen Stock Exchange from 2001 to 2005, Yuan, Xiao and Zhou (2008) confirm the important role of financial institutions (specially mutual funds) as delegated monitors in firm performance improvement for economies where the system of corporate governance and investor protection is not well established. For emerging countries where the establishment of the social secure system and state retirement planning is at an early stage, sustaining and accumulating private wealth remains crucial. As the life time financial planning emerges as clients’ preferred wealth management pattern (Tomecek (2003)), the enhancement of product range in line with the development of IFSP becomes a core competence of modern financial services institutions to serve “emerging middle class”. Moreover, family-owned conglomerate groups and bank-commerce interlink are more predominant in emerging countries which provides the pre-condition for the development of IFSP. Saunders and Walter (1996) first identify the deregulation trend and redesign of financial system towards the universal-bank based financial system in the Asia Pacific region. Claessens (2002) investigates extensively the relevance of IFSP for developing countries. He outlines the dominant role of banks in developing countries and the current existence of 19 financial conglomerates in emerging countries and concludes the gains of IFSP outweigh the costs due to higher costs from asymmetric information, higher coordination needs for large projects and higher concentration of skills in emerging economies. 4.2. Limitations The main concern of the introduction of IFSP in transition and emerging countries lies in the question, if the regulatory authority is capable to oversight the complicated intra-group monetary and information flows in a financial conglomerate to avoid and detect fraud or corruption to protect the deposits’ interest and ensure the functionality of the whole financial system, if the legal enforcement can efficiently protect the interest of small investors through litigation, and if the market discipline with sufficient transparency and competition mechanism can be established to prevent abuses from conflicts of interest. Even in developed countries with established systems of supervision, litigation and market discipline as in the USA, scandals such as the WorldCom case happened with no less participation of large integrated financial institutions. How to prevent such abuses in emerging countries with less skilled resources remains the core question in developing IFSP in emerging countries. The model of relationship banking in emerging countries bears the risk that political influences and closer family ties instead of market forces could determine the distributions of finance resources. Another risk lies in overregulation which at the same time restricts the synergy potential of scale and scope economies. Section 5: Conclusions IFSP has the inherent advantage to leverage client information for multiple services in relationship banking over client’s life time. Scale and scope economies enable IFSP the ability of providing superior financial services at lower costs. Closer bank-client relationship and banks’ equity holding in IFSP better foster firms’ growth and provide firms finance insurance in times of financial distress. The risk diversification effect through the combination of various service lines contributes to the system stability in a financial system with IFSP model. However, diseconomies of scale and scope due to inability to manage complex large-scope operations and conflicts of interest in various roles of IFSP as debt holder, equity holder, advisor, sales broker, asset manager and insurer at the same time can diminish the benefits of IFSP and lead to overall conglomerate discount. The large size of IFSP to reach scale economy can induce more moral hazard of banks’ risk taking and the spill-over of failure in one business line or one bank can put the whole financial safety-net in danger. The overall results show no superiority of one system over another. Probably it is a case of path dependency and history. As the conclusion of Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic (2000) in their analysis of the influence of market-based and bank-based financial systems in 40 countries between 1989 and 1996 on firm external financing: The legal contract environment other than the type of financial system is the premier determinant of firms’ availability of external financing. The evaluation of the integration or segregation of financial institutions should always be embedded in the regulatory and managerial context. How to balance the benefits and costs of IFSP to better serve economic growth remains the core question for financial system design and strategic banking management. 20 Developing IFSP can be of special relevance for emerging countries. The existing dominance of banking institutions and family-owned finance groups build the ideal basis to develop the integrated model. Leveraging the existing bank client basis and services can further stimulate the development of capital markets and insurance markets. In an integrated model, limited skills can be allocated more efficiently and inefficiencies from asymmetric information and higher coordination needs can be reduced. How to avoid the disadvantages and prevent abuses of conflicts of interest remains the core task of regulators in emerging countries. As China is an unique country in the world still with commercial bank law favoring segregated financial system and the current ongoing deregulation process on the incremental trial basis is progressing, understanding the benefits and costs of IFSP can be of special importance as the next cornerstone for China’s banking reform. To figure out the impact on business models and financial stability of the gradual deregulation process of China’s banking sector towards IFSP is of special interest for further research and of utmost importance for the ongoing smooth development of China’s financial system and macroeconomy. 21 References Allen, Franklin/Gale, Douglas (1999): ''Innovations in Financial Services, Relationships and Risk Sharing'', Management Science, Vol. 45 Allen, Linda/Jagtiani, Julapa (2000): ''The Risk Effect of Combination Banking, Securities and Insurance Activities'', Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 52 Altunbas, Yener/Molyneux, Phil (1996): ''Economies of Scale and Scope in European Banking'', Applied Financial Economics, Vol. 6 Barth, James R./Caprio, Gerard, Jr./Levine, Ross (2001): ''The Regulation and Supervision of Banks Around the World - A New Database'', The World Bank, working paper Barth, James R./Caprio, Gerard, Jr./Levine, Ross (2008): ''Bank Regulations Are Changing: For Better or Worse?'', The World Bank, working paper Benston, George J. (1994): ''Universal Banking'', The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 8 Ber, Hedva/Yafeh, Yishay/Yosha, Oved (2001): ''Confict of Interest in Universal Banking: Bank lending, Stock underwriting, and Fund Management'', Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 47 Biswas, Rita and Horst Loechel (2001) Recent Trends in U.S. and German Banking Industry: Convergence or Divergence?", in: Frankfurt School of Finance and Management (Hrsg.), Working Paper No. 29 Boot, Arnoud W. (2000): ''Relationship Banking: What Do We Know? '', Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 9 Boyd, John H./Graham, Stanley, L. (1986): ''Risk, Regulation and Bank Holding Company Expansion into Nonbanking'', Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Boyd, John H./Graham, Stanley, L. (1988): ''The Profitability and Risk Effects of Allowing Bank Holding Companies to Merge with Other Financial Firms: A Simulation Study'', Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, working paper Boyd, John H. (1999): ''Expansion of Commercial Banking Powers . . . or, Universal Banking is the Cart, not the Horse'', Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 23 Burghof, Hans-Peter (1999): ''Credit and Information in Universal Banking – a Clinical Study'', University of Frankfurt, working paper Cabral, Luis M. B./Santos, Joao A. C. (2001): ''Cross Selling and Banking Efficiency'', Federal Reserve Bank of New York, working paper Calomiris, Charles W. (1995): ''Universal Banking and the Finance of Industrial Development'', The World Bank, policy research working paper Campa, José Manuel/Kedia, Simi (2002): ''Explaining the Diversification Discount'', The Journal of Finance, Vol. 57 Chen, Zhian/Li, Donghui/Liao, Li/Moshirian, Fariborz/Szablocs, Csaba (2008): ''Expansion and Consolidation of Bancassurance in the 21th Century'', Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money Chen, Zhian/Li, Donghui/Moshirian, Fariborz/Tan, Jianzhong (2006): ''Does Bancassurance Add Value to Banks? - Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions between European 22 Banks and Insurance Companies'', China International Conference in Finance, conference paper Chong, Beng-Soon/Liu, Ming-Hua/Altunbas, Yener (1996): ''The Impact of Universal Banking on the Risks and Returns of Japanese Financial Institutions'', Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, Vol. 4 Claessens, Stijn (2002): ''Benefits and Costs of Integrated Financial Services Provision in Developing Countries'', University of Amsterdam, working paper Claessens, Stijn/Klingebiel, Daniela (2001): ''Competition and Scope Activities in Financial Services'', The World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 16 Clark, Jeffrey A. (1996): ''Economic Cost, Scale Efficiency, and Competitive Viability in Banking'', Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 28 Cumming, Christine M./Hirtle, Beverly J. (2001): ''The Challenges of Risk Management in Diversified Financial Companies'', Economic Policy Review, Vol. 7 Demirguc-Kunt, Asli/Maksi, Vojislav (2000): ''Funding Growth in Bank-Based and MarketBased Financial Systems: Evidence from Firm Level Data'', The World Bank Policy Research, working paper Diamond, Douglas W. (1984): ''Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring'', The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 51 Dierick, Frank (2004): ''The Supervision of Mixed Financial Services Groups in Europe'', European Central Bank, Occasional Paper Series, No. 20 Dobbs, Kevin (2008): ''Prism of Financial Crisis Casts New Light on 'Universal' Debate'', American Banker, Vol. 173 Drucker, Steven/Puri, Manju (2005): ''On the Benefits of Concurrent Lending and Underwriting '', The Journal of Finance, Vol. 60 Edwards, Patrick (1998): ''Managing Risk and Capital in Financial Conglomerates'', Risk and Capital Management Conference of Australian Prudential Regulation Authority, conference paper Elsas, Ralf/Krahnen, Jan Pieter (2004): ''Universal Banks and Relationship with Banks'', The Germany Financial System, Oxford University Press Ely, David P./Robinson, Kenneth J. (2004): ''The Impact of Banks’ Expanded Securities Powers on Small-business Lending'', Review of Financial Economics, Vol. 13 Esen, Rita (2001): ''The Transition of German Universal Banks'', Journal of International Banking Regulation, Vol. 2 EU Financial Conglomerate Directive 2002/87/EC: http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/financial-conglomerates/supervision_en.htm Fernández, Ana I./González, Francisco/Suárez, Nuria (2008): ''How Institutions and Regulation Shape the Influence of Bank Concentration on Economic Growth. International Evidence'', 11th Symposium of Finance, Banking and Insurance, conference paper Ferrara, Peter J. (1990): ''International Trends in the Combination of Banking, Securities and Commerce'', Cato Journal, Vol. 10 Fields, L. Paige/Fraser, Donald R./Kolari, James W. (2007): ''Is Bancassurance a Viable Model for Financial Firms?'', The Journal of Risk and Insurance, Vol. 74 23 Fohlin, Caroline (2000): ''Banking Industry Structure, Competition, and Performance: Does Universality Matter?'', California Institute of Technology, social science working paper Freixas, Xavier/Lóránth, Gyöngyi/Morrision, Allan D. (2005): ''Regulating Financial Conglomerates'', National Bank of Belgium, working paper García-Herrero, Alicia/Vazquez, Francisco (2007): ''International Diversification Gains and Home Bias in Banking'', International Monetary Fund, working paper Gertner, Robert H./Scharfstein, David S. /Stein, Jeremy C. (1994): ''Internal versus External Capital Markets'', Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109 Hebb, Gregory M./Fraser, Donald R. (2002): ''Conflict of Interest in Commercial Bank Security Underwriting: Canadian Evidence'', Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 26 Heggestad, Arnold (1975): ''Riskiness of Investments in Non-bank Activities by Bank Holding Companies'', Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 27 Herrera, Anna Maria/Minetti, Raoul (2007): ''Informed Finance and Technological Change: Evidence from Credit Relationships'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 83 Hoshi, Takeo/Kashyap, Anil/Scharfstein, David (1990): ''The Role of Banks in Reducing Costs of Financial Distress in Japan'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 27 Institute of International Bankers (2007): ''Regulatory and Market Developments'', Institute of International Bankers Global Survey International Monetary Fund (2008): ''World Economic Outlook October 2008'' John, Kose/John, Teresa A./Saunders, Anthony (1993): ''Universal Banking and Firm Risk Taking'', Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 18 Johnson, William C./Marietta-Westber, Jennifer (2005): ''Universal Banking, Asset Management, and Stock Underwriting'', University of New Hampshire - Whittemore School of Business and Economics, working paper Johnson, Rodney N. /Meinster, David R. (1974): ''Bank Holding Companies: Diversification Opportunities in Non-bank Activities'', Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 1 Kanatas, George/Qi, Jianping (2003): ''Integration of Lending and Underwriting: Implications of Scope Economies'', The Journal of Finance, Vol. 58 Kang, Jun-Koo/Liu, Wei-Lin (2007): ''Is Universal Banking Justified? Evidence from Bank Underwriting of Corporate Bonds in Japan'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 84 Klein, Peter G./Zoeller, Kathrin (2003): ''Universal Banking and Conflicts of Interests: Evidence from German Initial Public Offerings'', University of Missouri Columbia, working paper Koeppl, Thorsten/MacGee, James (2005): ''What Banks Do and Markets Don’t: CrossSubsidization'', Queen's University, Department of Economics, working paper Krishnan, Karthik (2006): ''Universal Banking, Private Information, and Incentive Problems: What Do Ex-Post Lending Patterns Tell Us?'', European Finance Association 2006 Zurich meeting, conference paper Kroszner, Randall S./Strahan, Philip E. (2001): ''Bankers on Boards: Monitoring, Conflict of Interest, and Lender Liability'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 62 Laeven, Luc/Levine, Ross (2007): ''Is There a Diversification Discount in Financial Conglomerates?'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 85 24 Laux, Christian/Walz, Uwe (2007): ''Cross-Selling Lending and Underwriting: Scope Economies and Incentives'', Goethe University Frankfurt, working paper Lehar, Alfred /Randl, Otto (2003): ''Chinese Walls in German Banks'', University of Vienna, working paper Litan, Robert E. (1987): ''What Should Banks Do? '', The Brookings Institution Ljungqvist, Alexander /Marston, Felicia /Starks, Laura T./Wei, Kelsey D./Yan, Hong (2007): ''Conficts of Interest in Sell-side Research and the Moderating Role of Institutional Investors'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 85 Loechel, Horst and Xiaoju Zhao (2006), The Future of Banking in China, Frankfurt Massa, Massimo/Rehman, Zahid (2008): ''Information Flows within Financial Conglomerates: Evidence from the Banks-Mutual Funds Relation'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 89 Mehran, Hamid/Stulz, René M. (2007): ''The Economics of Conflicts of Interest in Financial Institutions'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 85 Montoriol-Garriga, Judit (2008): ''Bank Mergers and Lending Relationships'', European Central Bank, working paper Nurullah, Mohamed/Staikouras, Sotiris K. (2008): ''The Separation of Banking from Insurance: Evidence from Europe'', Multinational Finance Journal, Vol. 12 Petersen, Mitchell A./Rajan, Raghuram G. (1994): ''The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data'', The Journal of Finance, Vol. 49 Puri, Manju/Rocholl, Jörg (2008): ''On the Importance of Retail Banking Relationships'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 89 Puri, Manju (1996): ''Commercial Banks in Investment Banking Conflict of Interest or Certification Role?'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 40 Puri, Manju (1999): ''Commercial Banks as Underwriters: Implications for the Going Public Process'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 54 Ramirez, Carlos D. (1999): ''Did Glass-Steagall Increase the Cost of External Finance for Corporate Investment? Evidence from Bank and Insurance Company Affiliations'', The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 59 Rich, Georg /Walter, Christian (1993): ''The Future of Universal Banking'', Cato Journal, Vol. 13 Rime, Bertrand/Stiroh, Kevin J. (2003): ''The Performance of Universal Banks: Evidence from Switzerland'', Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 27 Ritter, Jay R./Zhang, Donghang (2007): ''Affiliated Mutual Funds and the Allocation of Initial Public Offerings'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 86 Santos, Joao A. C./Rumble, Adrienne S. (2006): ''The American Keiretsu and Universal Banks: Investing, Voting and Sitting on Nonfinancials' Corporate Boards'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 80 Saunders, Anthony/Walter, Ingo (1996): ''Financial System Design in the Asia Pacific Context: Costs and Benefits of Universal Banking'', Management Decision, Vol. 34 Saunders, Anthony/Walter, Ingo (1994): ''Universal Banking in the United States'', Oxford University Press Schmidand, Markus M./Walter, Ingo (2008): ''Do Financial Conglomerates Create or Destroy Economic Value?'', New York University, working paper 25 Steffen, Sascha/Fischer, Markus (2008): ''Lending Relationships and Loan Rate Smoothing'', Goethe University Frankfurt, working paper Tomecek, Christopher W. (2003): ''Integrated Financial Services: The New Client Preference Model'', National Underwriter Vennet, Rudi Vander (1998): ''Cost and Profit Dynamics in Financial Conglomerates and Universal Banks in Europe'', Ghent University, working paper Villalonga, Belén (2000): ''Does Diversification Cause the "Diversification Discount"? '', University of California, dissertation Wall, Larry D./Eisenbeis, Robert A. (1984): ''Risk Considerations in Deregulating Bank Activities'', Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Vol. 69 Walter, Ingo (2003): ''Strategies in Financial Services, the Shareholders, and the System: Is Bigger and Broader Better?'', Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services Walter, Ingo (2006): ''Reputational Risk and Conflicts of Interest in Banking and Finance: The Evidence So Far'', New York University, working paper Wilmarth, Arthur E. Jr. (2005): ''Die Universal Bank Play a Significant Role in the U.S. Economy's Boom-and-Bust Cycle of 1921-33, a Preliminary Assessment'', Current Developments in Monetary and Financial Law, Vol. 4 Yasuda, Ayako (2007): ''Bank Relationships and Underwriter Competition: Evidence from Japan'', Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 86 Yuan, Rongli/Xiao, Jason Zezhong/Zou, Hong (2008): ''Mutual Funds Ownership and Firm Performance: Evidence from China'', Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 32 26