HEC MONTRÃAL Ãcole affiliée à l`Université de Montréal Essays on
Transcription
HEC MONTRÃAL Ãcole affiliée à l`Université de Montréal Essays on
HEC MONTRÉAL École affiliée à l'Université de Montréal Essays on the Dominant Logics of Strategizing within the Multinational Enterprise: A Regional Perspective par Ali Taleb Service de l'enseignement du Management Thèse présentée à la Faculté des études supérieures et postdoctorales en vue de l'obtention du grade de Philosophiae Doctor (Ph.D.) en Administration des Affaires. Spécialisation en Management Septembre 2012 © Ali Taleb, 2012 HEC MONTRÉAL École affiliée à l'Université de Montréal Cette thèse intitulée : Essays on the Dominant Logics of Strategizing within the Multinational Enterprise: A Regional Perspective Présentée par : Ali Taleb a été évaluée par un jury composé des personnes suivantes : Professeur Louis Hébert HEC Montréal Président du comité de surveillance Professeur Ari Van Assche HEC Montréal Président-rapporteur Professeur Rick Molz Concordia University – John Molson School of Business Membre du jury Professeur Zhan Su Université Laval Examinateur externe Professeure Sophie Marmousez HEC Montréal Représentante du directeur de HEC Montréal. © Ali Taleb iii Résumé Cette thèse se compose de trois essais complémentaires dont l'objectif commun est d'explorer les logiques dominantes des activités d’élaboration des stratégies au sein des entreprises multinationales. Le premier essai est théorique. Nous y proposons un cadre conceptuel qui contraste et intègre les rationalités économique, institutionnelle et politique qui façonnent les décisions stratégiques. Nous mettons ainsi en évidence le fait que la mobilisation conjointe de ces trois lentilles analytiques renforce leurs capacités explicatives individuelles. Le modèle proposé permet de décortiquer davantage la « boîte noire » des activités d’élaboration de stratégies et de faire le lien entre les aspects « marché » et « non marché » de la stratégie. En plus d’apporter des contributions spécifiques à la littérature, cet article sert d'introduction conceptuelle aux deux études empiriques incluses dans cette thèse. Le second essai est sous forme d’une étude qualitative exploratoire. On y examine comment six pratiques stratégiques développées par la filiale canadienne d'une multinationale pharmaceutique ont été diffusées aux autres filiales de la firme. Nous avons adopté l’approche de réplication d’études de cas pour examiner les processus de diffusion. En focalisant sur la dimension régionale des processus intraorganisationnels, cette étude apporte une contribution unique au débat actuel sur l’aspect régional des stratégies internationales des entreprises. Nous avons également mis en avant cinq propositions qui pourront être testées empiriquement. Le troisième essai propose une analyse quantitative des logiques dominantes des choix de localisation par les multinationales originaires des pays émergents. En effet, iv les études ancrées dans la rationalité économique expliquent les choix des pays hôtes des multinationales par la tendance de ces dernières à concentrer leurs activités dans des pays qui sont géographiquement proches de leurs pays d’origine. Ainsi, leur objectif est d’assurer l'efficacité économique de leurs opérations. D’autres études, plus récentes, suggèrent que les multinationales des pays émergents en particulier préfèrent s’installer dans des marchés dont les caractéristiques institutionnelles sont proches de celles de leurs pays d’origine. De ce fait, leur comportement est plutôt guidé par leur besoin de légitimité. Dans cette étude, nous avons examiné les effets respectifs des logiques d'efficacité économique et de légitimité institutionnelle sur les choix de localisation. Pour ce faire, nous avons analysé les configurations des réseaux des filiales de 203 multinationales des pays émergents. Les données empiriques confortent nos prédictions théoriques. Plus précisément, les choix des locations de ces firmes dans leurs régions d’origine sont guidés par la logique économique. Dans d'autres régions, elles arbitrent les deux logiques selon leurs degrés d’expérience internationale. Ces résultats contribuent de façon significative aux débats actuels sur le processus d'internationalisation des multinationales des pays émergents et sur la nature régionale des stratégies internationales des multinationales en général. Mots clés : Entreprise multinationale, logiques dominantes, diffusion de pratiques, choix de locations, logiques de formation des stratégies, stratégie régionale, stratégie globale, pays émergents. v Summary This thesis consists of three complementary essays whose common goal is to explore the dominant logics of strategizing activities within the multinational enterprise. The first paper is conceptual. It provides an analytical framework that contrasts and integrates the economic, institutional, and political rationalities of strategic decision making. We thereby highlight the increased explanatory power of the three logics when they are used as an integrated set of analytical lenses. The proposed framework helps unravel the “black box” of strategizing activities and bridges the gap between the market and non-market aspects of global strategy. In addition to making specific contributions to the literature, this essay serves as a conceptual introduction to the two empirical papers. The second essay consists of an exploratory qualitative study. We investigate how six strategizing practices developed by the Canadian subsidiary of a global pharmaceutical company diffused to sister subsidiaries. We followed a case-based replication approach and paid particular attention to the regional dimension of the diffusion mechanisms. This study makes a unique contribution to the current debate on the regional aspect of international strategy by examining its relevance to practice diffusion within the organization. We also put forward five propositions that can be tested empirically. In the third essay, we use quantitative data to analyze the dominant logics underlying location choices by multinational enterprises from emerging markets. The existing literature suggests that MNEs in general tend to focus their activities in nearby vi countries for economic efficiency reasons. More recent studies have found that emerging market multinationals, in particular, tend to seek legitimacy and thereby base their activities in markets with institutional conditions that are similar to or worse than those in their home countries. We examine the respective effects of economic efficiency and institutional legitimacy logics on location choices. To this end, we analyzed the configurations of the location networks of 203 emerging market multinationals and found general empirical support for our predictions. In particular, these firms tend to follow economizing logic in their home regions and a mix of both logics in other regions. The arbitration of the two logics in host regions is partly moderated by the firm’s degree of international experience. Our findings make important contributions to the current efforts to understand the internationalization process of emerging market multinationals and the regional aspects of international strategy. Keywords: Multinational enterprise, dominant logics, practice transfer, location choice, strategizing logics, regional strategy, global strategy, emerging markets vii Table des matières Résumé .................................................................................................................................. iii Summary ................................................................................................................................ v Table des matières ................................................................................................................ vii Liste des tableaux .................................................................................................................. ix Liste des figures ..................................................................................................................... x Liste des sigles et des abréviations........................................................................................ xi Dédicace ............................................................................................................................... xii Remerciements .................................................................................................................... xiii Introduction générale ............................................................................................................. 1 Chapter 1 – The Logics of Strategizing within Multinational Enterprises: Economic Efficiency, Social Legitimacy, and Political Power Abstract .................................................................................................................................. 4 1.1 Introduction ...................................................................................................................... 5 1.2 Studying Emergent Global Strategy within MNEs .......................................................... 6 1.2.1 The Time Dimension of Global Strategy .................................................................. 7 1.2.2 The Space Dimension of Global Strategy ................................................................. 8 1.2.3 Strategizing within the MNE .................................................................................. 10 1.3 Three Tales of Global Strategy ...................................................................................... 10 1.3.1 The Competitive Strategy Perspective .................................................................... 11 1.3.2 The Institutional Strategy Perspective .................................................................... 12 1.3.3 The Political Strategy Perspective .......................................................................... 14 1.4 The Logics of Strategizing within Multinationals ......................................................... 17 1.5 Conclusion ..................................................................................................................... 19 References ............................................................................................................................ 23 Appendices ........................................................................................................................... 27 Chapter 2 – Successful Diffusion of Local Strategic Practices within Multinational Enterprises: An Exploratory Study of Organizational and Institutional Factors in a Regional Context Abstract ................................................................................................................................ 28 2.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 29 2.2 Intra-MNE Isomorphism and the Diffusion of Local Practices ..................................... 31 viii 2.2.1 Multidimensional Nature of Practice Diffusion within Multinationals .................. 32 2.2.2 Institutional Perspective of Practice Diffusion within Multinationals .................... 35 2.3 Research Methods .......................................................................................................... 37 2.3.1 Research Setting and Design ................................................................................... 38 2.3.2 Sampling Strategy ................................................................................................... 40 2.3.3 Data Collection........................................................................................................ 41 2.3.4 Data Analysis .......................................................................................................... 45 2.4 Results: Isomorphic Drivers of Practice Adoption Across Regions .............................. 46 2.4.1 Role of the Regional Head Office and Subsidiaries in the Diffusion Process ........ 47 2.4.2 The Regional Dimension of Practice Diffusion ...................................................... 55 2.4.3 Vetting the Findings Through Theoretical Replication .......................................... 58 2.5 Discussion and Conclusions........................................................................................... 60 References ............................................................................................................................ 65 Appendices ........................................................................................................................... 68 Chapter 3 – Location Choices by Multinational Enterprises From Emerging Markets: Legitimizing versus Economizing Logic Abstract ................................................................................................................................ 70 3.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 71 3.2 Theoretical Foundations and Predictions ....................................................................... 73 3.2.1 Relatedness of Location Networks: Geography versus Institutions ....................... 74 3.2.2 The Logics of Location Arbitrage: Economizing versus Legitimizing .................. 77 3.2.3 Moderating Effects of the International Experience in Host Regions .................... 81 3.3 Research Methods .......................................................................................................... 82 3.3.1 Data Sample ............................................................................................................ 82 3.3.2 Variables and Measures .......................................................................................... 84 3.4 Analyses ......................................................................................................................... 89 3.5 Discussion ...................................................................................................................... 94 3.6 Conclusion ..................................................................................................................... 97 References .......................................................................................................................... 101 Appendices ......................................................................................................................... 105 Conclusion générale ............................................................................................................ xiv ix Liste des tableaux Table I Intégration conceptuelle des trois articles………………………………………..... 3 Table II The Logics of Strategizing within the MNE………………………….…………..... 27 Table III Characteristics of Practices……………………………….……………………..………. 68 Table IV Home Countries of the 203 EM-MNEs in the Sample……………………….. 105 Table V Variables, Measures and Data Sources………………………………………........ 106 Table VI Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix………………………………….. 107 Table VII Statistics on Geographic Prevalence……………………………………………….. 107 Table VIII Results of Regression Analyses………………………………………………………. 108 x Liste des figures Figure 1 Liens logiques entre les trois articles……………………………………………… 2 Figure 2 The Three Dimensions of Global Strategy of the MNE……………………… 27 Figure 3 Tri-dimensional Transfer Flows of Practices with the MNE……………... 69 Figure 4 Moderating Effects of Experience on the Relationship Between Economizing Logic and Geographic Prevalence in Host Regions…….. 109 xi Liste des sigles et des abréviations CEPII CIP DM DM-MNE DOI EDI EM EMAC EM-MNE EU FDI FSA GDP GIP GovInd GP HLM HQ ICC LCD LDC LRJ MNE MSL NAFTA OLI OS RIP RS SEC1 SEC2 SEC3 UNCTAD US WHO WTO Centre d’études prospectives et d’informations internationales Country integrated plan (practice) Developed markets Developed market multinational enterprise Degree of internationalization of a multinational enterprise Economic distance index Emerging markets Region including Europe, Middle East, Africa, and Canada Emerging market multinational enterprise European Union Foreign direct investment Firm-specific advantage Gross domestic product Global integrated plan (global variant of CIP) Governance indicator Geographic prevalence Hierarchical linear modeling Regional headquarters Intra-class correlation coefficient Least developed countries Least-developed countries Local research journal (practice) Multinational enterprise Market strategic leadership (practice) North American Free Trade Agreement Ownership-Location-Internalization framework (or "eclectic paradigm") Originator subsidiary Regional integrated plan (regional variant of CIP) Recipient subsidiary First secondary practice (functionally similar to CIP) Second secondary practice (functionally similar to MSL) Third secondary practice (functionally similar to LRJ) Conference on Trade and Development United States of America World Health Organization World Trade Organization xii Dédicace A mon grand-père qui a initié la première organisation multinationale que j’ai connue : Une famille globale qui s'étend désormais sur plusieurs continents. A mes parents qui ont travaillé si durement et si obstinément pour offrir à leurs enfants le meilleur cadeau qui soit : L’éducation. xiii Remerciements Je n’aurais jamais pu finir cette thèse sans les encouragements et l’aide d’un certain nombre de personnes. En premier lieu, je dois remercier mon directeur de recherche, le professeur Louis Hébert, dont la rigueur scientifique et le souci de rendre ses étudiants autonomes ont certainement façonné qui je suis devenu comme chercheurenseignant. Dr Hébert est l’un des rares directeurs de thèse que les étudiants soucieux de forger leurs propres chemins scientifiques rêvent de rencontrer. Mes sincères remerciements vont également aux membres de mon comité de thèse, le professeur Taïeb Hafsi et le professeur Rick Molz, qui m’ont prodigué des conseils constructifs et apporté le support moral pendant des moments de doute et d’incertitude qui caractérisent tout parcours doctoral. Sans leur gentillesse légendaire et leur générosité avec leurs temps si précieux, je n’aurais jamais pu finir ce travail. Je voudrais également remercier les membres de ma chère famille – parents, frères et sœur – qui ont toujours soutenu mon rêve de mener mes études universitaires à terme. Incontestablement, aussi bien mes professeurs que mes étudiants m’ont appris à relativiser l’importance de mes connaissances, à mesurer l’ampleur de ce qui nous reste à tenter d’expliquer en tant que chercheurs, et à demeurer humble face à la complexité du monde qui nous entoure. Enfin, je remercie l’équipe administrative de la direction pédagogique du doctorat ainsi que mes collègues et chers amis doctorants qui ont su rendre mon expérience montréalaise aussi agréable socialement qu’enrichissante intellectuellement. Je ne tenterai pas de nommer toutes les personnes qui ont contribué à la réalisation de ce rêve d’enfance par peur d’en oublier quelques-unes. Alors, je dirais simplement à tous mes proches et à tous mes amis : merci du fond du cœur ! Introduction générale Cette thèse est composée de trois articles dont l’objectif commun est d’explorer les logiques dominantes sous-jacentes aux activités de « stratégisation »1 au sein des firmes multinationales. Comme chacun des papiers inclut sa propre introduction, l’objectif de cette introduction générale est de répondre à la question suivante : comment les trois articles s’intègrent-ils pour former un tout cohérent ? Pour répondre à cette question, nous discutons tout d’abord les dimensions des activités de stratégisation et les logiques associées. Ensuite, à la lumière de cette discussion, nous expliquons comment les trois articles se complètent et s’intègrent sur les plans théorique et méthodologique. La stratégisation a été définie dans la littérature comme le processus de formation de stratégie (Johnson, Melin et Whittington, 2003). Conceptuellement, Whittington (2006) a suggéré que la stratégisation s’articule autour de trois éléments interdépendants : les praticiens, les pratiques et la praxis. Les praticiens sont ceux qui font la stratégie. Les pratiques réfèrent à comment ces derniers mobilisant des routines et des processus pour former les stratégies. La praxis, quant à elle, désigne ce que les praticiens font concrètement et en pratique. Dans cette thèse, nous examinons les stratégies des multinationales comme quelque chose qu’elles font plutôt que quelque chose qu'elles ont (Jarzabkowski, 2004). Dans les études empiriques, nous mettons l'accent sur le contenu et le processus de stratégisation. 1 Faisant écho à l’anglicisme « strategizing », nous utilisons le terme « stratégisation » pour designer l’ensemble des activités liées à la formation des stratégies au sein des organisations. Par conséquent, la stratégisation consiste en une série d’actions et de décisions à partir desquelles émergent des stratégies (Mintzberg et Waters, 1985). Il y a logique de stratégisation quand ces actions et ces décisions suivent une tendance comportementale constante au fil du temps. C’est pour cette raison que Bettis et Prahalad (1995:2) ont associé le concept de « logique dominante » avec « stratégie générique ». En nous appuyant sur les diverses conceptualisations de la stratégie globale des firmes multinationales dans la littérature, nous suggérons que les décideurs approchent les questions transfrontalières à travers trois lentilles analytiques : économique, institutionnel et politique. Le rôle du premier article est d’identifier les logiques primaires de stratégisation au sein des firmes multinationales. En plus des contributions générales à la littérature existante, cet article fournit un cadre analytique que nous utilisons pour structurer le travail théorique et empirique dans les deux autres articles. Article 2 Qualitatif Logiques de diffusion de pratiques Article 1 Conceptuel Logiques de stratégisation Article 3 Quantitatif Logiques de choix de locations Figure 1 Liens logiques entre les trois articles 2 Les deux derniers articles peuvent être considérés comme des applications empiriques du modèle proposé dans le premier article. Ils clarifient les conditions contextuelles dans lesquelles une ou plusieurs des logiques identifiées dominent. Article 1 (Logiques dominantes de stratégisation) Éléments de stratégisation Processus Contenu Logiques de stratégisation Économique Institutionnelle Politique Article 2 (Diffusion de pratiques) Article 3 (Choix de locations) Table I – Intégration conceptuelle des trois articles Par soucis de parcimonie, nous n’avons pas inclus la logique politique dans le troisième article. Par ailleurs, les deux articles empiriques sont complémentaires étant donné que le premier concerne le processus de stratégisation (pratiques) alors que le second traite du contenu des stratégies (praxis). Références Bettis, Richard A. et C. K. Prahalad (1995). « The Dominant Logic: Retrospective and extension », Strategic Management Journal, vol. 16, no 1, p. 5-14. Jarzabkowski, Paula (2004). « Strategy as Practice: Recursiveness, Adaptation, and Practices-in-Use », Organization Studies, vol. 25, no 4, p. 529-560. Johnson, Gerry, Leif Melin et Richard Whittington (2003). « Micro strategy and strategizing: Towards an activity-based view », Journal of Management Studies, vol. 40, no 1, p. 3. Mintzberg, Henry et James A. Waters (1985). « Of Strategies, Deliberate and Emergent », Strategic Management Journal, vol. 6, no 3, p. 257. Whittington, Richard (2006). « Completing the practice turn in strategy research », Organization Studies, vol. 27, no 5, p. 613. 3 Chapter 1 – The Logics of Strategizing within Multinational Enterprises: Economic Efficiency, Social Legitimacy, and Political Power Abstract This conceptual paper examines the primary logics that shape strategy-making activities within multinational enterprises (MNEs). We propose an analytical model that clarifies and integrates the economic, institutional, and political dimensions of global strategy. By doing so, we illustrate the increased explanatory power of the underlying economizing, legitimizing, and politicizing logics as a complementary set of analytical lenses. This manuscript makes several contributions to the extant literature. In addition to the convenience of the proposed model in capturing the full depth and breadth of strategy-making dynamics, a logic-based approach to the analysis of the phenomenon allows for gaining more fine-grained insights into the “black box” of strategizing activities. It also helps bridge the market and non-market aspects of global strategy, which are generally viewed as distinct matters. While we conveniently used the pluralistic settings of the multinational firm to unravel the logics of strategizing, the proposed analytical framework can be used in various organizational contexts. Keywords Competitive strategy, institutional strategy, political strategy, strategizing logic, strategy-as-practice, corporate-subsidiary relationship. 1.1 Introduction The study of the global strategies of Multinational Enterprises (MNEs) is a complex and difficult task owing to the distributed disposition of their structures, the pluralistic nature of their environments, and the versatility of strategy making as an organizational phenomenon. While the term global implies some sort of consistency across the organization, multinationality reflects the diversity of environments in which MNEs – as integrated systems of local entities – operate. In line with the contingency view of strategic management, strategies are expected to vary from one country to another to ensure alignment with local requirements. In fact, Rumelt, Schendel, & Teece (1994) suggested that one of the most fundamental questions that students of strategic management must address is why strategies of firms vary across geographic space. We suggest that the pluralistic setting of the MNE is highly suitable for the exploration of such phenomena, especially in light of interactions between global strategy and local contexts as they both evolve over time. We concur with Ghemawat (2007) and assert that global strategy is not only a matter of a one-time choice between scale economies and local responsiveness; it is also about ongoing arbitrage of frequent conflicts that arise. This paper explores the dynamics underlying strategy-making mechanisms with three key assumptions in mind. First, strategy formation within MNEs is a multi-level process where the dynamics between the head office and business units play an instrumental role (e.g., Gupta & Govindarajan, 1984). Second, subsidiaries may engage in proactive activities to shape the global strategies of their parents in order to 5 enhance their power of influence across the organization (Bouquet & Birkinshaw, 2008). Lastly, strategies in general can hardly be implemented as initially formulated. Instead, the patterns of the strategies that are actually implemented emerge from the streams of ongoing actions and decisions (Mintzberg & Waters, 1985). Building upon these assumptions, our primary objective is to explore the fundamental logics underlying the emergence of global strategies within MNEs. To this end, we first discuss the concept of emergent strategy in the global context of the MNE. Second, we explore the dimensions of global strategy from both corporate and subsidiary perspectives. Then, we examine the primary logics underlying strategy-making activities within the MNE. Finally, we highlight the contributions and limitations of this paper before we conclude with possible avenues for future research. 1.2 Studying Emergent Global Strategy within MNEs The complexity of subsidiary corporate relationships, the variety of institutional contexts in which affiliates are embedded, and the unpredictable nature of business environments can only result in ongoing adjustments to the strategies of MNEs. Consequently, a careful examination of how ongoing decisions and actions crystallize into emergent global strategies within MNEs requires us to consider both temporal and spatial dimensions of strategy-making activities. 6 1.2.1 The Time Dimension of Global Strategy Formal strategies are instrumental managerial levers used by corporate leaders to induce their business units towards particular patterns of organizational and market behaviour. Nevertheless, such mechanisms have major limitations because the bearing of deliberate strategies over time is subject to ongoing and unpredictable evolutions in business environment (Eisenhardt & Brown, 1998; Mintzberg, 1987). Indeed, formal strategies are never realized as originally planned (Mintzberg & Waters, 1985) due to their very nature as an outcome of hypothetical forecasts and educated guesses, at best. Subsequent to the formulation of intended strategies, some elements may be omitted intentionally or implemented unsuccessfully (unrealized) while some others could be added (emergent) in response to recent changes in business environments. Thus, realized strategies are partly deliberate and partly emergent. The strategies that are actually implemented are in fact a combination of original strategic intents and a series of adjustments in the course of ongoing managerial decisions and actions. While the concept of emergent strategy is valuable in conceptualizing the nature of strategy within a single business unit over time, it is not clear how it applies in the pluralistic and distributed context of MNEs, especially in relation to the dynamics underlying subsidiary corporate relationships. Indeed, the strategies of a head office and its affiliates are not the results of two independent processes that evolve in parallel over time or even a sequence of administrative routines by the virtue of which subsidiary level strategies become “miniature replicas” (White & Poynter, 1984) of corporate strategy. In fact, local and global strategies are logically interdependent and 7 technically entangled regardless of the nature and degree of integration between the head office and its subsidiaries. Since global strategies emerge from streams of ongoing decisions and actions (Mintzberg & Waters, 1985) and given that strategy implementation takes place ultimately at the subsidiary level, global strategies may not be completely insulated from the consequences of local managerial activities. However, it is not clear from the extant literature how strategies emerge from ongoing decisions and how actions crystallize into dominant logics over time. 1.2.2 The Space Dimension of Global Strategy While time factor is the basis of Mintzberg's characterization of emergent strategy, the spatial aspect of the phenomenon was only assumed in international management research. We define the space dimension of global strategy as the focal organizational level in which particular decisions are made and specific actions are taken with the intention to influence an MNE’s strategy. For the purpose of this study, we identify three conceptual levels of analysis: corporate, subsidiary, and the corporatesubsidiary relationship. The corporate perspective assumes that the international organization of MNEs, and thus their global strategies, evolves organically as they expand beyond their home country. Stopford & Wells (1973), for instance, argue that MNEs undergo several “international structural stages” as they diversify their products and markets. As a result, their global strategies evolve along with the stages of their internationalization process. Building upon Chandler’s (1962) work on strategy and structure and Venon’s (1966) product cycle view of international investment and trade, Stopford & Wells 8 suggested that MNEs start with exports as their first means to enter a market and ultimately implement global matrix structures as their organization reaches a higher degree of complexity. Between the initial and final stages of this evolution, they may set up global strategic business units or regional divisions depending on the extent of their product diversification and on the proportion of international sales in the overall turnover. Essentially, this perspective views subsidiary mandates as the key materialization of global strategy at the local level. As such, head offices decide subsidiary roles as a part of their global strategies implementation scheme. The subsidiary perspective advocates that corporate strategies are essentially collections of subsidiary mandates, which are essentially driven by local factors. In this regard, Benito, Grogaard & Narula (2003) argued that the conditions of local environments such as economic and regulatory policies are the real drivers behind the scope of subsidiaries’ activities. Combined with locally developed competencies, host country factors determine the global roles of subsidiaries. Accordingly, head offices may only shape their global strategies by seeking to coordinate actions and facilitate synergies among autonomous affiliates. The corporate-subsidiary relationship perspective is based on two key assumptions. On the one hand, headquarters must coordinate activities (Roth, 1992), integrate value activities (Porter, 1986), and ensure knowledge sharing (Gupta & Govindarajan, 1994) across business units in order to achieve global efficiencies (Porter, 1986). On the other hand, subsidiaries need to be responsive to local constraints and expectations. 9 1.2.3 Strategizing within the MNE One of the reasons why strategy formation is an elusive phenomenon is because strategic thinking and action evolve constantly over time and space. While emergent strategy is the culmination of ongoing decisions and actions (Mintzberg & Waters, 1985) in terms of content, strategizing is about the processes of strategy making (Johnson, Melin, & Whittington, 2003) as strategies are made and remade (Whittington, 2006). Indeed, strategy is something MNEs do rather than something they have (Jarzabkowski, 2004), and there is a strategizing logic when those actions and decisions show a consistent pattern over time. This is the reason why Bettis & Prahalad (1995:2) associated the concept of “dominant logic” with “generic strategy”. In this paper, we focus on three prevailing perspectives of global strategy, clarify the associated rationalities, and discuss the underlying strategizing logics. 1.3 Three Tales of Global Strategy In his work on the Cuban Missile Crisis, Allison (1971) masterfully illustrated the interest of cross-analyzing complex phenomena through multiple lenses to enhance the intelligibility and accuracy of their examination. In the same vein, we discuss global strategy from three perspectives with reference to the multiple dualities that characterize corporate-subsidiary relationships (Knoben & Oerlemans, 2006). 10 1.3.1 The Competitive Strategy Perspective "Strategy is making trade-offs in competing […] Competitive strategy is about being different. It means deliberately choosing a different set of activities to deliver a unique mix of value." (Porter, 1996:3-4) Competitive strategy is about attaining competitiveness through product-market strategic positioning (Madhok, 1997:25). In the distributed context of the MNE, competitiveness also entails effective configuration and efficient coordination of activities globally (Porter, 1986). But, corporate efforts to achieve global synergies may be hindered by ongoing conflicts between corporate economic imperatives, which require global integration, and local political imperatives, which require subsidiaries to be responsive to host country expectations (Doz, 1980). The critical review of the existing literature shows that research on global strategy is intimately associated with the integration-responsiveness dilemma and with the configuration of subsidiary-parent relationships. Additionally, Ghoshal (1987:5) suggested that the integration-responsiveness framework is essentially a “conceptual lens for visualizing the cost advantages of global integration of certain tasks vis-à-vis the differentiation benefits of responding to national differences in tastes, industry structures, distribution systems, and government regulations.” Therefore, the corporate view of global strategy is closely associated with competitive strategy. Such conception of global strategy implies that economic efficiency is the primary driving force behind strategy making. While the head office may assign a global role to a subsidiary for economic reasons, organizations are also known to adopt structures, 11 procedures, or ideas for legitimacy rather than economic motives (Meyer & Rowan, 1977). Furthermore, subsidiaries must not be viewed as passive actors who implement corporate decisions without challenging them. In fact, they may even engage in entrepreneurial actions aimed at gaining or getting rid of a global mandate (Birkinshaw, 1996) and thus influence the global strategy of their parents (Jarillo & Martinez, 1990). We contend that while, on the one hand, headquarters focus on economic efficiencies to justify their very existence through coordinated synergies and economies of scale, on the other hand, subsidiaries exploit institutional discrepancies between their host and home countries to justify their distinctiveness and enhance their autonomy from the head office. In line with Lawrence’s (1999) suggestions about the institutional strategies of firms to shape institutional structures, we explore how the subsidiary level institutional strategies may help shed some light on the evolution of global strategies over time and space. 1.3.2 The Institutional Strategy Perspective "The concept of 'institutional strategy' describe[s] patterns of organizational action that are directed toward managing the institutional structures within which firms compete for resources, either through the reproduction or transformation of those structures." (Lawrence, 1999:1) MNEs are “plurality of systems” where both intended actions and unintended consequences of social action shape institutional structures (Melin, 1992). In this sense, they are meta-institutions (Hedlund, 1986) that create, shape, and undo internal institutional arrangements while dealing with both internal and external 12 institutional actors. Some institutional elements have always been present in international business studies (Dunning & Lundan, 2008), and competitive strategy acknowledges the importance of institutional contingencies in general. However, institutional strategies go beyond the recognition of the fact that organizations are not just a bunch of resources and economic ratios (Scott, 2008); they imply that organizational actors take proactive actions to manage institutional structures based not only on the nature of institutional settings but also on the type of resources that are available to them (Lawrence, 1999). The characteristics of resources are of paramount importance because institutional strategies and competitive strategies require different sets of capabilities in that “institutional strategy demands the ability to articulate, sponsor and defend particular practices and organizational forms as legitimate or desirable, rather than the ability to enact already legitimated practices or leverage existing social rules…” (Lawrence, 1999:3). Local competitive strategies are intimately shaped by the nature of subsidiary mandates as granted by headquarters. In addition, subsidiaries deal with non-market actors who may influence – directly or indirectly – market institutional structures. The proactive actions taken by subsidiaries to shape internal arrangements and norms (organizational structure, subsidiary mandate…) and external institutional settings (market and non-market institutions…) are all part of their institutional strategies. Unlike competitive strategies which are essentially driven by economic efficiency to maximize performance, institutional strategies are guided by legitimacy needs to secure organizational survival (Meyer & Rowan, 1977). In fact, legitimacy is a more useful lever of influence than economic arguments or hierarchical power when it 13 comes to the positioning of subsidiaries within the internal markets of MNEs (Birkinshaw, 1997). The competitive and institutional components of global strategy are both complementary and conflicting. In particular, competitive strategy is essentially driven by corporate impetus while institutional strategy reflects subsidiary distinctiveness. This is important because the content of strategic decisions emerges from internal dynamics (Narayanan & Fahey, 1982) including conflicts that arise from struggles for organizational power and control (Mudambi, 2011a). The arbitration of such local-global tensions and the reconciliation of goal-obstacle conflicts (Avakian, 1999) involves significant political work and influence. 1.3.3 The Political Strategy Perspective "The political context for viewing strategy is useful not only because it exposes the docility in conventional management concepts of strategy, but because it elucidates the behaviors that are most effective in the goalobstacle conflict that is at the heart of strategy." (Avakian, 1999:7) Organizations are political entities with coalitions of interests (Mintzberg, 1985) so the full appreciation of their strategies requires us to understand their organizational politics (Pfeffer, 1992). Multinational firms, in particular, are “political structures” whose role is to “organize employees, customers, suppliers, consultants, brokers, counsellors, etc.” (Forsgren, 2008:140) in order to achieve specific objectives. Their political actions cross over organizational boundaries and involve both internal and external stakeholders. As independent organizations, MNEs are in the political arena 14 (Djelic & Quack, 2003) where political games take place (Anand, Gardner, & Morris, 2007). As a part of a broader ecosystem, they may be powerful political actors as they engage in political influence processes (Aplin & Hegarty, 1980) to both respond to external pressures (Murtha & Lenway, 1994) and promote their own goals by shaping their political environment (Avakian, 1999; Capron & Chatain, 2008). To achieve these objectives, they adopt proactive, defensive, anticipatory, or reactive political strategies (Oliver & Holzinger, 2008a), or a combination of several asymmetric strategies (Bonardi, 2004:3) for that matter. Indeed, the political dimension of global strategy has evolved from the status of contingencies to be taken into account when competitive strategies are being formulated (Doz, 1980; Ghoshal & Nohria, 1993) into an opportunity set that can be leveraged by strategic leadership (2008b). In general terms, political strategy is defined as "activities taken by organizations to acquire, develop and use power to obtain an advantage (a particular allocation of resources) in a situation of conflict” (Mahon, 1993:196, as cited by Capron & Chatain, 2008). It has also been rightly called “influence strategy” (Birnbaum, 1985:1) because politics is all about “inducement and getting people to do what they were otherwise not inclined to do through the exertion of influence” (Avakian, 1999:1). Given the deterministic nature of the economic rationality employed by headquarters and the formal power granted by organizational structures to corporate leadership, local managers may have no other option but to try political influence by using legitimating arguments and local institutional specificity to promote subsidiary agendas. Political tensions, including those related to strategizing activities, are particularly present within MNEs due in part to the divergence of corporate and 15 subsidiaries’ interests and to the diversity of host environments in which affiliates are embedded. -----------------------------------Insert Figure 2 about here. -----------------------------------In the pluralistic context of the MNE, political action has both internal-external and vertical-lateral dimensions (Farrell & Petersen, 1982). On the one hand, MNEs develop political strategies to shape their external political environment (Capron & Chatain, 2008) by the means of influences that are not achievable by the pure market pursuit of objectives to maximize economic returns (Oliver & Holzinger, 2008a). In so doing, firms employ both offensive and defensive political strategies (Bonardi, 2004) depending on firm characteristics, institutional factors, and levels of participation in the public policy-making process (Hillman, Zardkoohi, & Bierman, 1999). They may be initiated at the corporate level or by subsidiaries on behalf of their parents (Blumentritt & Rehbein, 2008; Blumentritt, 2003). On the other hand, subsidiaries may also engage in micro-politics, especially during strategizing activities (Narayanan & Fahey, 1982), in an attempt to attract corporate attention (Bouquet, 2005; Bouquet & Birkinshaw, 2008) and gain organizational power (Bower & Gilbert, 2007). The dependency of subsidiaries on corporate resources (Pfeffer, 1981) and the proactive efforts of subsidiaries to gain autonomy and global mandates (Birkinshaw, 1996; Delany, 2000; Moore, 2001) are examples of the reasons why power games are intrinsic to the management of MNEs from a subsidiary perspective (Dörrenbächer & Geppert, 2011). 16 In short, an MNE's global strategy may be analyzed from three perspectives – competitive, institutional, and political – each of which mobilizes a distinct rationality (Table II). Thanks to their complementarity, they enhance the explanation power of each other when they are integrated to analyze the logics underlying strategizing activities within the MNE. 1.4 The Logics of Strategizing within Multinationals Competitive strategy is about making trade-offs to deliver a unique mix of value to customers (Madhok, 1997; Porter, 1996). By focusing on economic efficiency, competitive strategy follows economizing logic. In addition to its position in the outer competitive market (Porter, 1980), the MNE can be conceptualized as an internal market (Birkinshaw, 1998) where hierarchies play a major role in the profit maximization process. While he suggested that strategy making is no more than economizing, Williamson (1991) also recognized that firms sometimes use strategizing tactics to influence economizing outcomes (Madhok, 1997). This implies that strategizing is about more than just economizing. In fact, strategy-as-practice scholars conceptualize strategy making as a socially accomplished activity (Jarzabkowski, Balogun, & Seidl, 2007). Unlike economizing logic which is associated with profit maximization, legitimizing logic seeks to establish social legitimacy that is instrumental to the very survival of organizations (Scott, 2008). This is why firms develop strategies to ensure compliance with external institutional requirements (Oliver, 1991) or undertake more proactive institutional work (Lawrence & Suddaby, 2006) to shape market institutions to their 17 advantage (Williamson, 1985). MNEs manage to mitigate economic contingences while increasing institutional legitimacy through "strategizing ploys" (Williamson, 1991). By doing so, they integrate market and non-market considerations into strategizing activities (Hillman & Hitt, 1999) and bridge the gap between market and social institutions. Interactions between the firm and its market environment are governed by market or private agreements whereas the public, stakeholders, government, the media and other public institutions are the main intermediaries in non-market settings (Hillman & Hitt, 1999). -----------------------------------Insert Table II about here. ------------------------------------ While some scholars (e.g., Peng, 2002) made a plausible case for complementarity between economic and institutional views of global strategy in recent years, the political dimension is still largely assumed, ignored, or treated as an aberration in strategic management literature (Mudambi, 2011b). One may confound, for instance, institutional work (Lawrence & Suddaby, 2006) with political action, but the underlying logics are clearly distinct and the scope of political work goes beyond shaping institutions. Politicizing activities reach out to stakeholders in the wider community, both within and outside the organization. Contrasting with economizing and legitimizing logics, the politicizing logic underlying micro-politics within the MNE focuses more "on how things really work rather than on how they should work" (Avakian, 1999:1). In addition, Mudambi (2011b) suggested that political tensions arise from agency relationships within the MNE, on the one hand, and from resource dependency between business units and the external environment, on the other hand. 18 Therefore, political games are closely linked to legitimacy seeking (Weber, 1968) and competition for strategic resource acquisition (Mudambi, 2011b). In terms of resource acquisition, firms compete in two types of markets – factor markets and political markets (Capron & Chatain, 2008). In addition to factor markets, where they acquire ready-for-use resources, firms manoeuvre in political markets to induce policymakers to produce policies that serve their economic interests (Keim & Zeithaml, 1986). This substantiates complementarity between economizing and legitimizing logics as well as it asserts the role of political dynamics, and of politicizing logic, in bridging the gap between efficiency and legitimacy rationalities. Clearly, the political dimension of strategizing activities deserves specific attention at least for the reason that "people sometimes manipulate the behaviour of others to accomplish their goals" (Avakian, 1999:1). As shown in Table II, each of the identified dimensions of global strategy mobilizes a distinctive logic that is rooted in a different rationality. The question is not whether they are complementary and reinforce the explanatory power of each other, but rather how they interact and when one may prevail over the others. 1.5 Conclusion This paper focuses on exploring the fundamental logics underlying global strategizing activities within the MNE. We suggest that global strategy is better understood when it is analyzed from three distinct and complementary perspectives: economic, institutional and political. These strategic dimensions reflect the conflicting yet legitimate logics and rationalities that are being mobilized by the head office and 19 subsidiaries while arbitrating global contingences and local preferences. We argue that these logics must be considered both individually and jointly in order to fully understand how strategies emerge in the pluralistic context of the MNE. This manuscript makes several contributions to strategic management, international business, and organizational theories literature. First, we proposed a conceptual model that combines economic efficiency, social legitimacy, and political power rationalities in an integrated set of lenses to analyze how strategies come about within MNEs. Such frameworks proved to be handy in capturing the full depth and breadth of the phenomenon and, thus, in assessing strategy contents and processes in a systematic and comprehensive way. Second, building upon the premises of the above model, we introduced a logic-based view of strategic analysis within organizations. Strategy-as-practice scholars suggested that strategizing activities are conceptually at the intersection of practices, practitioners, and praxis (Jarzabkowski et al., 2007). We suggest that a close analysis of the logics that drive such activities would be helpful in gaining additional insights into the “black box” of strategizing activities. While each of the primary logics – economizing, legitimizing, and politicizing – may be associated with one of the dimensions of global strategy, we argue that the way they interact over time and space is a defining attribute of strategizing activity. This is in fact instrumental to their conceptual integration and analytical complementarity. Another contribution of this paper resides in the fact that the proposed model and underlying logics help bridge market and non-market strategies, which are generally viewed as distinct matters (Hillman & Hitt, 1999). Finally, while we conveniently used the pluralistic settings of the multinational firm to unravel the logics of strategizing, our 20 findings are highly transposable to other organizational contexts. Additionally, Prahalad & Bettis’ (1986) work on strategic dominant logics showed that the patterns or logics of decision making may be identified at both the individual and group levels. We expect the students of strategic management to find the conceptual division of global strategy into three complementary dimensions (Figure 2) helpful in operationalizing future studies. They may use the triplet of strategizing logics we identified as analytical lenses to explore other organizational phenomena. Finally, the use of dominant logics (Prahalad & Bettis, 1986) in the study of strategizing activities provides scholars with a practical conceptual tool to bridge multiple levels of analysis. Future studies of strategy-making phenomena are likely to benefit from adopting a logic-based approach to study, for instance, interactions among the components of the conventional strategy-as-practice framework – that is, practices, practitioners, and praxis (Whittington, 2006). The model should also be appealing to practitioners of management. Decision makers are naturally receptive to integrated frameworks that enhance conceptual clarity, simplify managerial intricacies, and help make sense of complex situations. Furthermore, the prevalence of certain dominant logics in particular contexts, especially economizing logic at the corporate level and legitimizing logic at the subsidiary level, should attract the attention of managers to the special arbitration role of politics in pluralistic settings such as the MNE, where stakeholders have competing yet legitimate interests. 21 We suggest that future studies should explore how micro-politics affect the selective mobilization of economizing and legitimizing arguments during strategizing activities. The tension between economizing and legitimizing rationalities may also be further investigated with particular focus on the mechanisms used by subsidiaries to influence their parents. If economizing logic predominates at the corporate level and legitimizing logic is essentially local in nature then politicizing logic might well be a conceptual bridge between the two. One may view politicizing work as a reconciliation mechanism between local institutional strategy and corporate competitive strategy. Another aspect of strategizing activities that deserves particular attention is related to how the underlying logics evolve through time and across geography. In line with the ongoing debate on the global-regional nature of international strategy, it would be of particular interest to explore the evolution of strategizing logics from a regional perspective. Finally, strategy researchers have discussed the interaction between strategy content and process in the past. It would be helpful to explore the emergence of strategizing logics from a content-process dichotomy perspective. The investigation of how strategizing practices and praxis shape strategy contents would be useful in completing the practice turns in strategy research (Whittington, 2006). 22 References Allison, G. T. 1971. Essence of decision: explaining the Cuban missile crisis. Boston: Little, Brown. Anand, N., Gardner, H. K., & Morris, T. 2007. Knowledge-based innovation: Emergence and embedding of new practice areas in management consulting firms. Academy of Management Journal, 50(2): 22. Aplin, J. C., & Hegarty, W. H. 1980. Political Influence: Strategies Employed by Organizations to Impact Legislation in Business and Economic Matters. Academy of Management Journal, 23(3): 438-438. Avakian, P. N. 1999. Political realities in strategy. Strategy & Leadership, 27(6): 4248. Benito, G. R. G., Grogaard, B., & Narula, R. 2003. Environmental influences on MNE subsidiary roles: economic integration and the Nordic countries. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(5): 443. Bettis, R. A., & Prahalad, C. K. 1995. The Dominant Logic: Retrospective and extension. Strategic Management Journal, 16(1): 5-14. Birkinshaw, J. 1996. How multinational subsidiary mandates are gained and lost. Journal of International Business Studies, 27(3): 467. Birkinshaw, J. 1997. Entrepreneurship in Multinational Corporations: The characteristics of subsidiary initiatives. Strategic Management Journal, 18(3): 207. Birkinshaw, J. 1998. Corporate entrepreneurship in network organizations: How subsidiary initiative drives internal market efficiency. European Management Journal, 16(3): 355. Birnbaum, P. H. 1985. Political Strategies of Regulated Organizations as Functions of Contest and Fear. Strategic Management Journal, 6(2): 135-135. Blumentritt, T., & Rehbein, K. 2008. The Political Capital of Foreign Subsidiaries: An Exploratory Model. Business and Society, 47(2): 242. Blumentritt, T. P. 2003. Foreign subsidiaries' government affairs activities: The influence of managers and resources. Business and Society, 42(2): 202-233. Bonardi, J.-P. 2004. Global and political strategies in deregulated industries: the asymmetric behaviors of former monopolies. Strategic Management Journal, 25(2): 101-101+. Bouquet, C. 2005. Building global mindsets: An attention-based perspective. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan. Bouquet, C., & Birkinshaw, J. 2008. Weight versus voice: How foreign subsidiaries gain attention from corporate headquarters. Academy of Management Journal, 51(3): 577. Bower, J. L., & Gilbert, C. G. 2007. From resource allocation to strategy (1st paperback [ed.]. ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Capron, L., & Chatain, O. 2008. Competitors' Resource-Oriented Strategies: Acting upon Competitors' Resources through. Interventions in Factor Markets and Political Markets. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 33(1): 97-121. 23 Chandler, A. D. 1962. Strategy and structure: chapters in the history of the industrial enterprise. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Delany, E. 2000. Strategic development of the multinational subsidiary through subsidiary initiative-taking. Long Range Planning, 33(2): 220. Djelic, M.-L., & Quack, S. 2003. Governing globalization-bringing institutions back in. In M.-L. Djelic, & S. Quack (Eds.), Globalization and Institutions: Redefining the Rules of the Economic Game: 1-14. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Dörrenbächer, C., & Geppert, M. 2011. Politics and power in the multinational corporation : the role of institutions, interests and identities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Doz, Y. L. 1980. Strategic Management in Multinational Companies. Sloan Management Review, 21(2): 27. Dunning, J. H., & Lundan, S. M. 2008. Institutions and the OLI paradigm of the multinational enterprise. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 25(4): 573. Eisenhardt, K. M., & Brown, S. L. 1998. Competing on the edge : strategy as structured chaos. Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press. Farrell, D., & Petersen, J. C. 1982. Patterns of Political Behavior in Organizations. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 7(3): 403403. Forsgren, M. 2008. Theories of the multinational firm : a multidimensional creature in the global economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Ghemawat, P. 2007. Managing Differences: The Central Challenge of Global Strategy. Harvard Business Review, 85(3): 58. Ghoshal, S. 1987. Global strategy: An organizing framework. Strategic Management Journal (1986-1998), 8(5): 425. Ghoshal, S., & Nohria, N. 1993. Horses for courses: Organizational forms for Multinational Corporations. Sloan Management Review, 34(2): 23. Gupta, A. K., & Govindarajan, V. 1984. Business unit strategy, managerial characteristics, and business unit effectiveness at strategy implementation. Academy of Management Journal (pre-1986), 27(000001): 25. Gupta, A. K., & Govindarajan, V. 1994. Organizing for knowledge flows within MNCs. International Business Review, 3(4): 443-457. Hedlund, G. 1986. The Hypermodern MNC -- A Heterarchy? Human Resource Management, 25(1): 9. Hillman, A. J., & Hitt, M. A. 1999. Corporate political strategy formulation: A model of approach, participation, and strategy decisions. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 24(4): 825-842. Hillman, A. J., Zardkoohi, A., & Bierman, L. 1999. Corporate political strategies and firm performance: Indications of firm-specific benefits from personal service in the U.S. government. Strategic Management Journal, 20(1): 67-67. Jarillo, C. J., & Martinez, J. I. 1990. Different roles for subsidiaries: the case of multinational corporations in Spain. Strategic Management Journal (19861998), 11(7): 501. Jarzabkowski, P. 2004. Strategy as Practice: Recursiveness, Adaptation, and Practicesin-Use. Organization Studies, 25(4): 529-560. Jarzabkowski, P., Balogun, J., & Seidl, D. 2007. Strategizing: The challenges of a practice perspective. Human Relations, 60(1): 5. 24 Johnson, G., Melin, L., & Whittington, R. 2003. Micro strategy and strategizing: Towards an activity-based view. Journal of Management Studies, 40(1): 3. Keim, G. D., & Zeithaml, C. P. 1986. Corporate Political Strategy and Legislative Decision Making: A Review and Contingency Approach. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 11(4): 828-828. Knoben, J., & Oerlemans, L. A. G. 2006. Proximity and inter-organizational collaboration: A literature review. International Journal of Management Reviews, 8(2): 71-89. Lawrence, T. B. 1999. Institutional strategy. Journal of Management, 25(2): 161. Lawrence, T. B., & Suddaby, R. 2006. Institutions and institutional work. In S. C. Hardy, & T. B. Lawrence (Eds.), Handbook of Organization Studies, 2nd Edition ed.: 215-254. London: Sage. Madhok, A. 1997. Economizing and strategizing in foreign market entry. In P. W. Beamish, & J. P. Killing (Eds.), Cooperative strategies: North American Perspectives, 1st ed., Vol. 1: 25-. San Francisco: New Lexington Press. Mahon, J. F. 1993. Shaping issues/manufacturing agents: Corporate political sculpting. In B. M. Mitnick (Ed.), Corporate political agency: 187-212. Newbury Park, CA: Sage. Melin, L. 1992. Internationalization as a strategy process. Strategic Management Journal, 13: 99. Meyer, A., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology: 83. Mintzberg, H. 1985. The Organization as Political Arena. The Journal of Management Studies, 22(2): 133-133. Mintzberg, H. 1987. The strategy concept I: Five Ps for strategy. California Management Review, 30(1): 11. Mintzberg, H., & Waters, J. A. 1985. Of Strategies, Deliberate and Emergent. Strategic Management Journal, 6(3): 257. Moore, K. J. 2001. A strategy for subsidiaries: Centres of excellences to build subsidiary specific advantages. Management International Review, 41(3): 275. Mudambi, R. 2011a. The MNC as a political organization. In C. Dörrenbächer, & M. Geppert (Eds.), Politics and power in the multinational corporation : the role of institutions, interests and identities: xviii. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mudambi, R. 2011b. The MNC as a political organization. In C. Dörrenbächer, & M. Geppert (Eds.), Politics and power in the multinational corporation: The role of institutions, interests and identities: xvii-xix. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Murtha, T. P., & Lenway, S. A. 1994. Country capabilities and the strategic state: How national political institutions affect multinational corporations' strategies. Strategic Management Journal, 15(01432095): 113-113. Narayanan, V. K., & Fahey, L. 1982. The Micro-Politics of Strategy Formulation. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 7(1): 2525. Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic Responses to Institutional Processes. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 16(1): 145. 25 Oliver, C., & Holzinger, I. 2008a. The Effectiveness of Strategic Political Management: A Dynamic Capabilities Framework. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 33(2): 496-520. Oliver, C., & Holzinger, I. 2008b. The Effectiveness of Strategic Political Management: A Dynamic Capabilities Framework, Vol. 33: 496-520: Academy of Management. Peng, M. W. 2002. Towards an Institution-Based View of Business Strategy. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 19(2/3): 251. Pfeffer, J. 1981. Power in organizations. Toronto: Pitman. Pfeffer, J. 1992. Managing with power : politics and influence in organizations. Boston, Mass.: Harvard Business School Press. Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive strategy: Techniques for analyzing industries and competitors. New York: Free Press. Porter, M. E. 1986. Changing Patterns of International Competition. California Management Review, 28(2): 9. Porter, M. E. 1996. What is strategy? Harvard Business Review(NovemberDecember). Prahalad, C. K., & Bettis, R. A. 1986. The Dominant Logic: A new linkage between diversity and performance. Strategic Management Journal, 7(6): 485-501. Roth, K. 1992. International Configuration and Coordination Archetypes for... Journal of International Business Studies, 23(3): 533. Rumelt, R. P., Schendel, D., & Teece, D. J. 1994. Fundamental issues in strategy: a research agenda: Harvard Business School Press (Boston, Mass.) Scott, W. R. 2008. Institutions and organizations : ideas and interests (3rd ed.). Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage Publications. Stopford, J. M., & Wells, L. T. 1973. Managing the multinational enterprise. International Executive, 15(2): 9-11. Vernon, R. 1966. International investment and international trade in the product cycle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80(2): 190-207. Weber, M. 1968. Economy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology. New York Bedminster Press. White, R. E., & Poynter, T. A. 1984. Strategies for Foreign-Owned Subsidiaries in Canada. Business Quarterly (pre-1986), 49(2): 59. Whittington, R. 2006. Completing the practice turn in strategy research. Organization Studies, 27(5): 613. Williamson, O. 1991. Strategizing, economizing, and economic organization. Strategic Management Journal, 12(S2): 75-94. Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting: pp.1-67. New York: Free Press. 26 Appendices Figure 2 – The Three Dimensions of Global Strategy of the MNE Table II – The Logics of Strategizing within the MNE Strategic Dimension Strategizing logic Competitive Strategy Economizing Rationality of Efficiency action Disciplinary anchor Economics Institutional Strategy Legitimizing Political Strategy Politicizing Legitimacy Influence Sociology Politics Context shaping Conflict Key motivation Profit maximization Basis of interaction Exchange Organizational survival Conformity Organizational view Sample work Market Community Arena Porter (1996) Lawrence (1999) Avakian (1999) Strategic level Global (macro) Local (micro) Local-Global (mezzo) Market orientation Market strategy Both market strategy (formal institutions) and nonmarket strategy (informal institutions) Nonmarket strategy 27 Chapter 2 – Successful Diffusion of Local Strategic Practices within Multinational Enterprises: An Exploratory Study of Organizational and Institutional Factors in a Regional Context2 Abstract In this exploratory qualitative study, we examine how subsidiary-level strategic practices diffuse to sister organizational units within multinational enterprises (MNEs). We use a case-based approach to investigate the diffusion of multiple strategic practices developed by the Canadian subsidiary of a large MNE with particular interest in the regional dimension of the phenomenon. The results of our fine-grained analysis of data make several contributions. Firstly, the study sheds some light on bottom-up and peer-to-peer transfers of practices. Secondly, it unravels the three-pillar model of isomorphism as autonomous forces and establishes the empirical link between isomorphism and practice diffusion. Thirdly, it fosters the current debates on the regional nature of international strategy from a practice transfer perspective. Finally, we submit five propositions for future empirical testing. All these findings have important theoretical and practical implications. Keywords Practice diffusion, organizational isomorphism, regional strategy, organizational region, geographic region. This paper has benefited from comments from attendees of competitive sessions at the Academy of Management (2010) and Strategic Management Society (2011) meetings. 2 2.1 Introduction In this empirical paper we investigate how intra-organizational isomorphic forces foster the successful diffusion of practices from a subsidiary to its peers within the same multinational enterprise (MNE). Practice transfers are widely associated with the efficiency and performance of MNEs (Kostova, 1999) because the diffusion of routines and best practices are generally regarded as critical to the ability of an organization to develop sustainable competitive advantages (Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1987). We focus our investigation on subsidiary-level strategic practices with particular interest in the regional dimension of transfer mechanisms. Strategic practices have been defined by Kostova (1999:3) as those “believed to be of strategic importance for the firm—believed to reflect the core competencies of the firm and to provide a distinct source of competitive advantage that differentiates the firm from its competitors.” We concur with the spirit of this characterization and define local strategic practices as tools and processes specifically developed by subsidiaries to formulate or implement local strategic objectives. The extant literature on the diffusion of such practices spans a wide range of perspectives. While comprehensive reviews on literature on knowledge transfer are provided elsewhere (e.g., Argote, McEvily, & Reagans, 2003; Minbaeva, 2007), two important observations are of relevance to our study. The first is related to the external environment of the MNE and the second to its internal dynamics. 29 On the one hand, the pluralistic nature of the MNE makes it an interesting laboratory for the study of practice transfers. Practices carry institutional imprints in them, so similarities and differences between originator and recipient subsidiaries are instrumental to a successful transfer (Kostova, 1996). This is why a high institutional distance between the country of origin and the country of destination may hinder their successful transfer (Kostova & Roth, 2002). Since relative institutional proximity has been widely assumed within geographic regions (e.g., Arregle, Beamish, & Hébert, 2009; Rugman, 2005), practice transfer between countries that belong to the same geographic region are likely to succeed. Unlike other management phenomena such as the geographic aggregation of a firm’s economic activity (Rugman & Dossett, 2005), intra-organizational diffusion of practices has not been explored from a regional perspective. On the other hand, the motivations underlying top-down transfers of strategic practices within organizations are essentially driven by economic efficiency logic. That is, headquarters deploy tools and processes across the company with the primary intention of facilitating cross-organizational synergies and creating firm-specific competitive advantages (Kostova, 1999). From an inter-firm perspective, subsidiaries of foreign firms tend to mimic local competitors as a means of overcoming their liability of foreignness when they are faced with significant uncertainty in a host country (Zaheer, 1995). While mimesis is essential to practice diffusion including within the firm, we contend that using a full set of isomorphic pressures that also accounts for normative and coercive forces (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983) will help advance our understanding of the multi-dimensional diffusion mechanisms within the 30 MNE. Studying isomorphic forces with the MNE network is relevant because isomorphism is rooted in institutional fields (Glynn & Abzug, 2002) and the MNE itself has been conceptualized as an institutional field formed of its subunits (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999; Rosenzweig & Singh, 1991; Xu & Shenkar, 2002). Accordingly, the central objective of this study is to unravel the isomorphic dynamics underlying the successful transfer of local strategic practices with particular interest in their regional dimension. To this end, we first review some fundamental concepts relevant to the multi-dimensional diffusion of local practices within MNEs. Then, we describe the research site, empirical design, and strategies for data collection and analysis. Next, we discuss the results and put forward several propositions that can be tested empirically. Finally, we discuss the implications and limitations of our contributions before we suggest possible avenues for future research. 2.2 Intra-MNE Isomorphism and the Diffusion of Local Practices This study is concerned with intra-organizational flows of strategic practices from a subsidiary perspective. We view the MNE in three different ways. First, we conceptualize it as an interconnected network (Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1990) of transnational social spaces (Morgan, 2011). Second, we conceptualize it as an internal market (Birkinshaw, 1997) where affiliates engage in cross-border economic transactions. Finally, we view it as a political arena (Djelic & Quack, 2003) in which subsidiaries endeavour to attract corporate attention (Bouquet & Birkinshaw, 2008) and strive to gain global mandates (Birkinshaw, 1996). Thanks to the mobilization of 31 the analytical lenses that are associated with the three conceptualizations—namely institutional, economic, and political—we are able to gain a deeper understanding of the multidimensional phenomenon of practice diffusion within MNEs (Allison, 1971). 2.2.1 Multidimensional Nature of Practice Diffusion within Multinationals International management literature has traditionally emphasized the central role of the head office with regard to the dissemination of practices within its network of subsidiaries. The key premise is that corporate leadership needs to coordinate actions (Roth, 1992), integrate value-creating activities (Porter, 1986), and foster knowledge sharing (Gupta & Govindarajan, 1994) in order to achieve global synergies across business units (Porter, 1986). Strategic organizational practices in particular constitute a subset of knowledge assets that are valuable for dissemination across the organization (Nelson & Winter, 1982; Szulanski, Jensen, & Lee, 2003). Their diffusion is generally associated with top-down flows, which are typically monitored by head office. The dynamics underlying such flows are unique in that head offices often take advantage of the power of formal structures and control of resources to thrust the global deployment of practices such as quality management (e.g., Kostova, 1996). Nevertheless, the structural power that is associated with the hierarchical MNE (Hedlund, 1986) does not necessarily lead to the actual adoption of practices by subsidiaries. In reality, business units may pretend to comply with corporate requirements while ignoring them or even acting against them (Meyer & Rowan, 1977). That is why other organizational and relational elements are instrumental to the success of top-down transfers (Kostova, 1999). 32 While factors such as commitment, identity and trust take into account both local and global dimensions of corporate subsidiary relationships, they essentially consider subsidiaries as recipients in a cascading process. The factors identified above as drivers of practice diffusion may not be relevant to – or at least apply differently in – situations where subsidiaries are not recipients but originators of such practices. When the MNE is viewed as a hierarchical system, the successful diffusion of practices involves significant political power. This is because the degree of a subsidiary’s compliance with corporate pressures may have critical consequences, especially in terms of resource acquisition (Anand, Gardner, & Morris, 2007). Additionally, power tensions are structurally unbalanced between the head office of an MNE and its affiliates. As a result, corporate-subsidiary tensions may not be experienced or perceived in the same way from the two sides of the relationship. Therefore, the success of direct transfers between originator and recipient subsidiaries is also dependent upon their respective weights within the MNE network (Bouquet & Birkinshaw, 2008). The relative importance of a subsidiary’s role in practice diffusion is particularly evident when the MNE is viewed as an internal market (Birkinshaw, 1997) within which subsidiaries import and export organizational practices (Birkinshaw, 1999; Zaheer, 1995). When there is no involvement of the head office in intra-organizational transfers, subsidiaries mobilize more persuasive means than structural power to export their practices to their peers. 33 In addition to the political power of organizational structures and to the economic efficiency incentives of internal markets, subsidiaries may rely on legitimizing arguments and leverage the loosely coupled nature of organizational networks (Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1990) to diffuse their practices. Indeed, MNEs are “social communities that specialize in the creation and internal transfer of knowledge” (Kogut & Zander, 2003:1) and informal structures may constitute powerful substitutes to hierarchies as a source of organizational power. Head office does not need to be involved in all practice transfers; only specific circumstances may call for corporate impetus to ensure fast diffusion and crossorganizational consistency and efficiency. ------------------------------------Insert Figure 3 about here. ------------------------------------Figure 3 illustrates how practices diffuse within MNEs following three directions: bottom-up, top-down, and lateral. In line with the Scandinavian institutionalism literature, we use the term practice borrowing when direct transfers take place between originator and recipient subsidiaries. Diffusion may also occur through a corporate head office in two steps. First, there will be a bottom-up practice escalation from the original subsidiary to the head office whose role becomes the facilitation of transfers. Then, the head office will cascade the practice to subsidiaries following a top-down deployment approach. The existing literature on practice diffusion has essentially assumed the head office to be the originator of practices without paying much attention to where they were actually created in the first place. This study attends to the three dimensions of diffusion, but focuses primarily on the roles of subsidiaries as originators and recipients. The role of the head office may be 34 restrained to some sort of process facilitation. The distinction is essential because the motivations and arguments of head offices may differ depending on whether they act as originator or intermediary. The examination of intra-organizational mechanisms requires a more fine-grained analysis of micro-institutional dynamics than the country-level factors such as institutional distance that are generally used to explain the diffusion phenomenon (Kostova & Roth, 2002). In particular, we know very little about the relationship between institutional isomorphism and practice diffusion (Boxenbaum & Jonsson, 2008), including within the MNE. 2.2.2 Institutional Perspective of Practice Diffusion within Multinationals MNEs are meta-organizations with deep roots in multiple and often dissimilar institutional contexts. Hence, they represent complex inter-institutional systems (Thornton & Ocasio, 2008) where competing institutional logics shape the strategic choices of decision makers (Peng, 2002). For at least this reason, the explicit distinction between institutional effects and other factors is likely to be useful (Dunning & Lundan, 2008) to the understanding of socially embedded phenomena such as practice transfers. The diffusion of practices is typically associated with institutionalization processes because their internalization does not occur in a social vacuum (Kostova, 1999). Institutions themselves have been defined as widely diffused practices (Lawrence, Hardy, & Phillips, 2002) and institutional factors play a critical role in the successful diffusion of practices within the MNE. For instance, Kostova & Roth (2002) suggested 35 that low institutional distances between the home and host countries of foreign subsidiaries foster the adoption of corporate practices. This is due essentially to the fact that institutional proximity leads to normative integration (Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1988) and consequently to efficient cross-organizational transfers (Birkinshaw, 1997; Kostova, 1999). Additionally, foreign subsidiaries tend to mitigate their liability of foreignness (Zaheer, 1995) by imitating the practices of local firms (e.g., Rosenzweig & Singh, 1991) especially when they venture into unfamiliar institutional contexts. What is not clear, however, is whether such behaviour is replicated by peer subsidiaries within an MNE Network. This study strives to fill in this gap by considering the full spectrum of isomorphic dynamics – including mimetic, normative, and coercive pressures (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983) – while analyzing the diffusion mechanism. By doing so, we give the causal relationship between isomorphism and diffusion the full attention it deserves and yet has never received in the past (Boxenbaum & Jonsson, 2008). By examining how proto-institutions (Lawrence et al., 2002) like strategic practices emerge and diffuse across the MNE, we can appreciate how stakeholders advance their respective agendas through the promotion, endorsement, adoption, and institutionalization of strategizing routines and tools. Lastly, several recent empirical findings suggest that organizational phenomena may be guided by regional logics (e.g., Arregle et al., 2009; Nachum & Song, 2011). As a result, key drivers of market behaviour such as liabilities and competitive advantages seem to have at least a regional dimension to them. Since institutional proximity is key to practice transferability (Kostova & Roth, 2002) and geographic regions are often 36 assumed to be relatively homogeneous from an institutional perspective (Arregle et al., 2009; Rugman, 2003), practice transfers within geographic regions are more likely to occur and succeed. Accordingly, it would be helpful to examine such premises in light of actual empirical situations. More specifically, this study aims to answer two main questions: How do intraorganizational isomorphic forces foster the diffusion of local strategic practices from a subsidiary to another within the same MNE? And, do the region of origin and/or the region of destination matter to the successful transfer of such practices? 2.3 Research Methods In this qualitative study we contrast and compare the evolution of several strategic practices within the same MNE. In line with the above research questions, we use local strategic practices as our primary unit of analysis. The choice of strategic practices was driven by two primary reasons. First, senior managers suggested during the exploratory phase of this study that such practices represent a major lever that subsidiaries use to influence the global strategies of their parents. Typically, local strategic practices include activities, processes, and tools used by subsidiaries to form and execute local strategies. Second, strategic practices are found to be convenient for investigation because they are most “likely to be formalized at some point so that they can be diffused more easily in the organization” (Kostova, 1999:3). In particular, associated archival data are rich enough for fine-grained ex-post analysis. 37 2.3.1 Research Setting and Design The empirical investigation took place in Healthcare Canada3, the Canadian subsidiary of a global pharmaceutical company. The setting is particularly suitable for the study of strategic practices from a subsidiary perspective for several reasons. First, Healthcare Inc. is a large MNE that is present in over 100 countries. Subsidiaries are clustered into regions based on a mix of geographic, economic, institutional, and political consideration. The Canadian subsidiary belonged to the EMAC (Europe, Middle East, Africa, and Canada) region while the US market is so large that the country was considered as a full region by itself. This is important because the diffusion of practices may involve political games (Anand et al., 2007) and they are more balanced when they take place among equals. Second, the industry is equally attractive to the study of intra-organizational phenomena because sales and research functions are of equal importance in researchdriven pharmaceuticals. Sales generate the much-needed cash to invest in research and development while research outcomes feed product pipelines and hence lead to sales. Canada is considered to be a strategic market and the subsidiary has important sales and research mandates within its region. Accordingly, it must be both globally integrated and locally responsive, and hence have a fairly balanced relationship with headquarters. Research activities are highly specialized, capital intensive, and require global arbitrage. Conversely, sales drivers are essentially local because the industry is We have disguised the actual names of the firm, informants, and practices to preserve confidentiality. The following pseudonyms are used: Healthcare Local (HCL) for the Canadian subsidiary, Healthcare Regional (HCR) for the regional head office, and Healthcare Global (HCG) for corporate head office. 3 38 highly regulated by local governments. That is the reason why research functions are generally integrated and sales operations commonly decentralized within researchdriven firms in the pharmaceutical industry. Finally, the strategic practices we investigated in this study have all been transferred successfully from the Canadian subsidiary to other subsidiaries of Healthcare Inc. We focus on the medical affairs department because it is a key service provider to both sales and research functions. This is important because the practices developed by this department are at the crossroad of diverse organizational flows and political games. As illustrated in Table III, we privileged diversity over homogeneity in sampling to develop theories that are deeply rooted in fine-grained data (Harris & Sutton, 1986; Santos & Eisenhardt, 2009). Accordingly, we developed multiple cases to generate well-grounded theories that may not be otherwise deduced from extant theories alone. By focusing on a single organization, we mitigate the risk of confounding the effects of organizational characteristics (Lawrence et al., 2002). Specifically, we adopted an abductive approach (Dubois & Gadde, 2002; Yin, 2003) and thus alternate inductive and deductive logics to collect information, analyze data, and generate theory. Accordingly, we used a loose framework to guide our entry to the empirical world (Miles & Huberman, 1994) while increasing the analytical generalizability (Yin, 2003) of resulting theories. This design is particularly suitable for the study of the phenomenon at hand because existing theory is developed enough to help us structure our investigative approach while taking advantage of the richness of available data without being over-constrained by our presuppositions. Indeed, theoretical frameworks are found to be useful as general conceptual guidelines for 39 case studies as far as they allow the investigator to preserve the richness of the data collected and stay open to the emergence of counterintuitive findings (Miles & Huberman, 1994; Yin, 2003). 2.3.2 Sampling Strategy The sampling strategy is purposeful and theoretical (Pratt, 2009). We used a mix of literal and theoretical replication design (Yin, 2003) to generate theory that is grounded both conceptually and empirically. Literal replication helps explain the conditions under which practice transfers occur between originator and recipient subsidiaries while theoretical replication is meant to vet the conditions under which such transfers may not take place. For literal replication, we conducted an in-depth analysis of the processes leading to the transfer to three primary practices. We used them, along with existing theories, to shape our preliminary propositions and finetune the conceptual model as theory emerged from the data. The primary practices were created by three different individuals within the Canadian medical affairs team. They were all successfully adopted by foreign subsidiaries yet followed different organizational paths during their respective diffusions. The purpose of this literal replication is to analyze variations rather than compare the three instances with one another. The fact that these practices are not independent and take place in the same organizational setting increases their individual contributions to the understanding of the phenomenon (Anand et al., 2007). Once we derived a robust theoretical framework and the associated propositions from the initial three cases, we used a supplementary set of three confirmatory practices for theoretical replication in order to corroborate these findings. It is expected that 40 the theoretical replication produces different yet predictable results (Yin, 2003) in line with the theory that results from the initial literal replication. Confirmatory practices have been suggested by our informants as potentially transferable across the organization but did not actually diffuse as expected. While the study of multiple incidents does not pretend any statistical validation, it is important to understand the reasons for both successes and failures to reinforce the credibility of the findings. Finally, the selected number of six cases is appropriate for our study since we investigate processes that bridge multiple organizational levels within the same organization (e.g., Burgelman, 1983; Eisenhardt, 1989). In addition, the use of three primary practices for literal replication to develop theory and three others for theoretical replication to probe the initial findings is consistent with qualitative replication strategies that use multi-case design (Yin, 2003). Finally, the characteristics of the cases used for theoretical replication evolved as the study progressed due to the purposeful and theoretical nature of our sampling strategy (Pratt, 2009). 2.3.3 Data Collection The depth and extent of the data collected varied throughout the implementation of our research strategy. Essentially, the study went through three phases, which allowed for the incremental examination of the travel paths, organizational reaches, and isomorphic dynamics underlying the transfers of individual practices from the Canadian subsidiary to sister organizational units. 41 First, during the exploratory phase, we had access to the research field with no specific organizational phenomenon to be studied in mind except for a general interest in the means by which subsidiaries influence the global strategies of their parents. We conducted 20 interviews of 80 to 120 minutes each with diverse respondents within and outside of the focal team. The objective was to identify organizational phenomena worth investigating while keeping the above general theme of interest in mind. Accordingly, the questions were open ended and focused on interactions between the head office and subsidiaries. This led us to the identification of bottom-up transfers of local practices as a key instrument used by proactive subsidiaries to improve their social capital and gain political power within the organization. Two short lists of practices were derived from these interviews. The first one included 20 local practices that were adopted by foreign subsidiaries. The second had 15 practices that participants thought had the potential of being transferred to sister business units, even though this did not actually happen for various reasons which we will discuss afterward. Overall, the purpose of the exploratory phase was to identify the organizational phenomenon to be studied and determine the list of practices that are worth investigating in greater detail. In the second phase, we adopted a literal replication approach to develop a preliminary theoretical model and related propositions. The three primary practices have been chosen from the above list for several reasons. First, they have all been qualified by senior managers at the Canadian subsidiary as strategic given the key role they played in shaping local strategy. Furthermore, the strategic nature of the selected practices has been confirmed by respondents from the head office and recipient 42 subsidiaries alike. Second, they were all adopted by several organizational units across Healthcare Inc. Third, they were developed within the same department but not by the same person which minimizes the risk of confounding individual characteristics. Finally, they provided complementary insights into the phenomenon because they travelled through distinct organizational paths. We label these strategic practices as “primary” due to their central role in the literal replication process and hence in generating our initial theoretical predictions. As illustrated in Table III, the first primary practice was mandated by the regional head office of the firm as a new standard to be implemented across the affiliates within the region. Country Integrated Plan (CIP) is a comprehensive analytical framework that is meant to achieve crossfunctional strategic alignment at the subsidiary level. The framework has been developed by the Canadian subsidiary and was adopted first at the regional level and then globally. The second primary practice involved the head office as a facilitator rather than a driver of the diffusion process. Market Strategic Leadership (MSL) is a relationship management model whose purpose is to help the subsidiary build lasting relationships with its clients. This model has been developed in Canada and was adopted by some strategic subsidiaries in Asia, Europe, and the United States. The third and last primary practice is called Local Research Journal (LRJ). It is a Canadian model intended to provide scientific support to marketing and sales teams and was transferred directly from the originator subsidiary to small recipient subsidiaries in Latin America. The third and final phase of data collection consisted in probing the initial findings against three more practices. These were chosen from the second list of practices that 43 participants thought had the potential of being transferred to sister business units, even though this did not actually happen. We shall call these practices “secondary” because we used them in the theoretical replication phase only to confirm that different yet predictable results can be obtained if the conditions under which the primary practices were successfully diffused are not respected. The first secondary practice (SEC1) is functionally similar to CIP, but it didn’t diffuse due to lack of visibility. It was developed by a non-strategic subsidiary that had little access to corporate forums to promote the practice and get attention. The second secondary practice (SEC2) is functionally similar to MSL. It has not been adopted, despite the fact that some subsidiaries claimed interest in the functionality it provided, because it did not offer sufficient legitimacy incentives to strategic subsidiaries or sufficient efficiency incentives to non-strategic subsidiaries. The last secondary practice (SEC3) is meant to provide similar functionally to LRJ. It was not adopted due to the fact that the organization structure did not allow for interaction between Canadian and Japanese teams, which would supposedly be interested. To sum up, we have selected six practices by the end of the data collection phase. Three primary practices were chosen from the list of the twenty practices that have been successfully transferred across the MNE. Three secondary practices were selected from the list of the fifteen that participants thought had the potential of being transferred to sister business units, even though this did not actually happen. Throughout the three phases, we collected data from various sources and reconstructed the individual histories of the practices of interest. The data collected on individual practices included historical data such as the organizational purpose of 44 the practice, the key milestones of its diffusion, the actors involved in its creation and transfer, and the general arguments stakeholders used to export or import it. The primary source of data was semi-structured interviews involving informants who had a deep understanding of the practice in terms of both history and functionality. While the first interviews were conducted with the creators of individual practices whenever it was possible, we particularly sought diversity among respondents based on factors such as the level of tenure, seniority, and responsibility in order to obtain an accurate account of each practice’s evolution and context. For each practice, the list of informants emerged over time and we asked every person we met to provide the names of individuals that could give additional insights into the diffusion of the practice under study. We undertook member validation and met as many respondents as possible until we reached saturation of information to verify the viability of resulting theories (Anand et al., 2007; Eisenhardt, 1989; Langley, 1999). Therefore, the lists of respondents were specific to individual practices. In addition to interviews, we solicited artifacts from the respondents during interviews as well as from our main contact for this study within the company. 2.3.4 Data Analysis Our data analysis strategy is threefold. First, we developed detailed descriptions of the three primary cases through the lens of our research questions (Eisenhardt, 1989; Santos & Eisenhardt, 2009): How do intra-organizational isomorphic forces foster the diffusion of local strategic practices from a subsidiary to another within the same MNE? And, do the region of origin and/or the region of destination matter to the successful transfer of such practices? For each case, we described the practice, 45 determined how it came about, when it happened, who was involved, and which subsidiaries adopted it (Anand et al., 2007; Lawrence et al., 2002). Second, we summarized the characteristics of the primary practices and the dynamics underlying their diffusion in Table III showing both differences and similarities amongst them. This allowed us to make some initial assumptions about theory and thus to guide our final step of data collection and analysis. Third, we developed summary cases of complementary practices and used caution in applying the theory that emerged from the primary set. This was a highly iterative process (Glaser, 1998; Glaser & Strauss, 1967) as we constantly switched between existing theory, case descriptions from interviews, and collected artifacts. By the end of this procedure, we have synthesized all individual cases into tables and diagrams (Miles & Huberman, 1994) to show visually how we moved from raw data to theory (Pratt, 2009). This was done while keeping in mind isomorphic pressures and motives of key actors to adopt, diffuse, or facilitate the transfer of practices within the organization. The interplay between data analysis and pattern identification helped shape the theoretical framework and associated propositions gradually (Eisenhardt, 1989). 2.4 Results: Isomorphic Drivers of Practice Adoption Across Regions In this section, we discuss our findings from the analysis of the six strategizing practices we have investigated. As discussed in the research methods section, we have used three primary practices in the literal replication and three secondary practices in the theoretical replication. 46 2.4.1 Role of the Regional Head Office and Subsidiaries in the Diffusion Process By identifying the organizational paths of diffusion, we have determined the nature of the respective roles of the regional headquarters (HQ) and subsidiaries in the process. The selected primary practices have all been transferred successfully from the Canadian originator subsidiary (OS) to recipient subsidiaries (RS) in various countries. Our data suggested that the nature and degree of involvement of the head office in transfers has varied from active mediator to relative moderator to passive observer. ------------------------------------Insert Table III about here. ------------------------------------The first strategic practice provides an example of corporate-mediated diffusion. The Country Integrated Plan (CIP) is a comprehensive and cross-functional strategic alignment framework that has been developed by the Canadian medical department to break down local organizational silos. One of the roles of the medical team is to bridge and align sales and research activities in order to foster cross-functional synergies. This practice has been diffused through the head office, which acted as an active mediator between the originator and recipient subsidiaries (OS HQ RS). The regional head office asked the Canadian team to present CIP as a best practice in a regional executive meeting. Following this presentation, the regional leadership endorsed the practice and mandated its implementation across all subsidiaries in the region. 47 Unsurprisingly, informants cited the exposure of this practice to executives at the corporate level as a key trigger of its diffusion. Without the involvement of a Canadian executive in the regional executive committee, CIP would have never been noticed and hence diffused. As a senior manager mentioned: Certainly, if I was not part of that meeting nobody would even know about [CIP]. And, I was invited because we are part of the core group of countries within the region […] Canada is viewed as a strategic market and we have an R&D team here, so we are more exposed to corporate executives. The reason why this informant was invited to the meeting is because the Canadian subsidiary is among the seven strategic subsidiaries within the region. To reinforce the criticality of the status of a subsidiary in making its practices visible, he went on to add: Subsidiaries that are not part of this committee may have interesting practices that could be useful to other subsidiaries […] There is always something interesting you can borrow from other countries, but how would you even know about their existence? That's a critical question. Accordingly, the strategic status of a subsidiary within the MNE network is instrumental to the propensity of its local practices to diffuse across borders. More formally, we propose: Proposition 1 (P1): Headquarters of MNEs are more likely to co-opt and mandate the diffusion of practices that are created by strategic subsidiaries than those developed by non-strategic subsidiaries. 48 In line with the tridimensional model (Figure 1) we discussed earlier, the corporatemediated diffusion of CIP took place in two steps – escalation and cascading. First, the head office undertook several actions to legitimize CIP as a global practice by making it “implementable in other countries”, according to an informant. While some tangible adjustments were made to different templates and processes to minimize the time necessary for local teams to use them, the legitimizing actions were essentially symbolic. As another respondent stated, the “fine-tuning consisted more in nitpicking on words than anything else.” An anecdotal illustration of the symbolic nature of global legitimization is the decision to replace the word “Canadian” by “Country” and thus maintain the original acronym of the practice (CIP) while making it country-neutral. An informant commented in this regard: In fact, these adaptations were essentially fine tunings rather than actual changes. The modifications were kept minimal […] For instance, we kept the same acronym but ‘C’ now stands for ‘Country’ instead of ‘Canadian’ originally. These adjustments were made in collaboration with potential recipient subsidiaries (RS) through conference calls, email communications, and electronic forums that were created specifically to serve this purpose. While recognizing the role of the Canadian team as the originator of CIP, the HQ positioned itself as a "proxy owner" of the practice. The legitimizing effort changed the perception of CIP by future RS from a subsidiary practice into an emergent institution that is embedded in both subsidiary and head office contexts. The positioning of the HQ as a quasi-owner of the practice allowed it to proceed to the second stage of mediated transfer – cascading. The 49 cascading process was as if CIP had been developed by the HQ. In addition to mandating the use of the practice as the “regional platform for strategic planning”, the regional head office reinforced the new standard by setting up support infrastructures. The Canadian subsidiary gained the mandate of supporting all recipient subsidiaries as they implemented the practice. The global head office also created regional (RIP) and global (GIP) integrated plans that were essentially consolidated variants of country-level CIPs. Consequently, the perception of the HQ’s appropriation of the local practice has been reinforced in the eyes of recipient subsidiaries. In reality, the escalation and cascading processes intertwined as they both occurred within a period of seven months. According to a head office informant, the local practice emerged to become a global corporate standard in such short time because: CIP was there at the right place and at the right time. It was cross-functional and reflected the need of subsidiaries for integration and teamwork… It was consistent with [the corporate] strategic objective to reinforce the cross-functional integration. We thought 80% of the elements were there so you just needed to make some adjustments and push it down the organization structure to be implemented locally. While the corporate office might need to coerce some subsidiaries to implement a particular practice, some might do so voluntarily. As suggested by recent studies (e.g., Kennedy & Fiss, 2009), mimesis is a key driver of practice adoption. A respondent from the originator subsidiary pointed this out: 50 Subsidiaries may adopt a practice right away […] when they see the positive outcomes and business value they may get out of it. What 'value' means is subject to interpretation though. Indeed, further discussions with informants suggested that the meaning of "positive outcomes and business value" may differ depending on the status of the recipient subsidiary. For instance, an executive commented when asked about the success factors of CIP: Regional executives [who were present at the meeting where CIP was first presented as a best practice] saw the value of the process and the platform [i.e. outcome]. The same executives sold it to their teams. We just made some changes to make it acceptable to other countries. And, he went on to add: Frankly, most of [strategic subsidiaries] already have similar processes that work well enough for them. But, we are part of a family […] and have got to show the example if this is going to become a global standard. I mean, as a major subsidiary, we want to show some leadership and play a role model here. What we do is watched and amplified. I mean it's not like a small site [i.e. subsidiary]. It is almost a moral obligation when you are considered by corporate people as a strategic site. Accordingly, we propose: Proposition 2a (P2a): Strategic subsidiaries are more likely (than non-strategic subsidiaries) to adopt their peers' practices for legitimacy reasons. 51 On the other hand, the second primary practice we studied illustrates well the reason why non-strategic subsidiaries might choose to adopt practices voluntarily. It provides a compelling example of lateral diffusion (OS RS) or borrowing of practice between subsidiaries in the absence of any head office involvement. Local Research Journal (LRJ) is a medical publication that was initially developed by the Canadian team. The purpose was to support the subsidiary’s marketing efforts. The articles published in LRJ did not pretend to reveal ground breaking research. Instead, they added value and appealed to many healthcare professionals because the articles addressed local healthcare issues based on credible research studies. Senior managers generally viewed LRJ as a good complement to other marketing, public relations, and promotional tools used in Canada. The practice did not gain the attention of strategic subsidiaries because healthcare professionals in major markets were more interested in cutting-edge research and global studies than in local publications. In contrast, several small subsidiaries in Latin America learned about the practice informally. Then, they decided to adapt the concept to their local markets. According to an informant: These small [recipient] subsidiaries liked the idea because the studies were acceptable to their local scientific community. The quality was good enough for them and this kind of studies are less expensive to do than the ones we can afford [in larger subsidiaries]. They certainly can't afford to do this for the sake of simply attracting attention or please the head office. 52 These subsidiaries have chosen to adopt the practice despite the fact that the HQ did not see value in mandating its global diffusion. Corporate leaders knew about the transfer of which they were passive observers. As an informant stated: [The head office] was not involved at all. I don’t think they care in this particular case. The key here is the utility of the practice to them. The question of cost [to adapt the practice to local needs] is also important. Again, these are small sites [subsidiaries] and their budgets are really limited. I don’t think they would adopt [LRJ] if this was not really, really relevant to their market… or if it was too expensive to adapt. Therefore, the subsidiaries adopted this particular practice because of its functional utility and relative efficiency in addressing their local needs. Hence, we posit: Proposition 2b (P2b): Non-strategic subsidiaries are more likely (than strategic subsidiaries) to adopt their peers' practices for efficiency reasons. The third primary practice is a good illustration of corporate-moderated diffusion whereby the HQ acted as a facilitator (HQ [OS RS]). Market Strategic Leadership (MSL) is a client-relationship management model that has been developed in Canada with the intention of providing scientific support to marketing teams. The objective was to nurture and maintain lasting relationships with healthcare professionals who are the ultimate prescribers of the company’s products to patients. The practice was recognized across the company as an innovative way of gaining and sustaining a comparative advantage in the local market. However, only large subsidiaries embraced the practice and sought help from the Canadian team to implement it. When 53 asked about the reasons why MSL is not as diffused as CIP, a Canadian informant responded: MSL was adopted by some countries but not all [...] because of the headcount and because it was not mandated by the top. You know, affiliates do their [cost-benefit] calculations so countries with small headcounts do not need to implement something like this. The role the HQ played in the diffusion of MSL is somewhat in between those played in the diffusion of CIP and LRJ. It provides new insights into the lateral diffusion phenomenon because it was adopted by a subset of both strategic and non-strategic subsidiaries. On the one hand, the HQ did not mandate the global adoption of the practice because it would not make sense in some countries, especially in those with relatively small markets and limited resources. Instead, it acted as a moderator of decisions on whether to implement it or not depending on the specifics of each country. On the other hand, the head office played an active role in the process by legitimizing MSL through strategic endorsement. For instance, the Canadian subsidiary gained the global mandate to support recipient subsidiaries during the implementation of the practice. The attention paid by the head office to MSL is attributed by several informants to the fact that the subsidiaries that can benefit from the practice were essentially large and based in strategic markets, mostly in Asia and Europe. As an informant highlighted: The head office didn't push for the diffusion of [MSL] but it was involved in it because several important subsidiaries in Asia wanted to implement it. Japan found it interesting when they saw it in Europe and then adopted it. I am not sure 54 it is useful in there though because their margins [of action] are relatively limited by local market regulations. Then followed smaller countries in the region; they found the idea of mixed marketing teams with scientific and sales people to be effective in getting appointments with busy doctors. This statement reiterates the effect of subsidiary status on the diffusion process by influencing corporate attention and shaping adoption motives. It also hints of the need to consider the mechanisms of transfer of practices across regions. 2.4.2 The Regional Dimension of Practice Diffusion The organizational structure of Healthcare Global Inc. played an instrumental role in the cross-border transfer of the three practices under investigation. For instance, CIP would never have been diffused across the EMAC region without the visibility it gained during the regional executive meeting held in Europe. The Canadian executive was invited to this meeting because both the Canadian and West European subsidiaries reported (in the organizational chart) to the same regional head office located in Germany. He was given the opportunity to present CIP because Canada was one of the "core subsidiaries" in this region. As a respondent noted: The reporting structure is important and the organizational chart defines the frequency of contacts with our peers in other countries. Before we were put in this region, we had far fewer opportunities to meet our colleagues in Europe. Now, we report to the same people, we receive the same instructions […] there are the same expectations so it's important that we work together. My boss also organized meetings last year so, yes, we ended up learning interesting things when we socialized with colleagues in these meetings. 55 In this regard, another informant stated: Sure, the way we are organized [into regions] makes it easier for a practice like CIP to get noticed and adopted by European subsidiaries […] especially those who are part of the [regional] executive committee because they get to talk frequently in different meetings. The diffusion has been linked by respondents to the way the regions are structured in the organizational chart of the firm. The fact that Canada was a member of an organizational region (EMAC) that included West European and African countries has triggered its adoption across the countries that formed the region. Hence, we propose: Proposition 3a (P3a): The transfer of a local practice is more likely to start when both recipient and originator subsidiaries are located in the same organizational region. For the purpose of this study, we use the term organizational region to designate the way the MNEs cluster their subsidiaries into regions in their organizational structure to ease corporate governance and foster synergies amongst affiliates. For instance, Healthcare Global Inc. put Canada in a virtual region (EMAC) that also included West European, Middle Eastern, and African countries based on a mix of institutional (e.g., regulations, spoken languages), economic (e.g., geographic proximity), and political (e.g., comparable market size) reasons. Regardless of the grouping logic underlying organizational structures, shared reporting relationships foster cross-country interactions and thus increase the visibility of practices. 56 However, the visibility of a particular practice through organizational structure is not a sufficient condition for its successful transfer. Indeed, practices carry institutional imprints from the environment in which they emerge. This is why institutional distance between their countries of origin and destination may foster or hinder their successful adoption (Kostova & Roth, 2002). Therefore, practice transfers between countries that belong to the same geographic region are likely to succeed since relative institutional proximity has been widely assumed within geographic regions (Arregle et al., 2009; Rugman, 2005). While organizational regions are specific to firms as they reflect their internal governance structures, geographic regions represent a more standard concept. Scholars have used standard classifications developed by international institutions (e.g. World Bank, UNCTAD, WTO, WHO) based on various criteria including economic, political, and institutional conditions to group countries into regions (Aguilera, Flores, & Vaaler, 2007; Osegowitsch & Sammartino, 2008; Peng & Pleggenkuhle-Miles, 2009). For example, the World Bank and UNCTAD have used the traditional six continents as the basis of their classifications. On the other hand, scholars (e.g., Arregle et al., 2009; Rugman, 2005) have used the clusters of the Triad concept (NAFTA, Europe, and South Asia) in their groupings. That being said, all the definitions of geographic regions share the premise of some sort of spatial contiguity of the countries that form them. The following comment by an American informant reflects the effect of geographic regions on diffusion of practices: The Canadian and USA markets are quite different in terms of size and healthcare system structure, but we have quite similar regulatory requirements. More importantly, we are neighbors so there is no time difference compared with 57 our European or Asian colleagues. This is why we quite often work together and share best practices even though head office didn't put us in the same region on the organization chart. Accordingly, we suggest: Proposition 3b (P3b): The adoption of a local practice is more likely to succeed when both recipient and originator subsidiaries are located in the same geographic region. 2.4.3 Vetting the Findings Through Theoretical Replication After using the three primary practices to generate the above hypotheses, we used a supplementary set of three secondary practices that have been suggested by our informants as potentially transferable across the organization but that did not actually diffuse (Table III). The first secondary practice (SEC1) was functionally similar to CIP but it did not diffuse for the simple reason that it did not gain exposure to head office executive and sister subsidiaries. It was developed by the Greek subsidiary, which is a member of the EMAC region but Greece is not viewed as a “strategic market”. According to a respondent: Sure, [SEC1] is similar to CIP but nobody knew about it. You simply can’t like something if you don’t even know it exists. Small subsidiaries have very little exposure if any to corporate folks. […] Large affiliates have more power, more frequent opportunities to talk about what they do and how they do things. They are engaged in the preparation of regional meetings too. 58 Therefore, SEC1 had fewer chances than CIP to get noticed and be adopted due to the lack of visibility that resulted from the non-strategic status of its originating subsidiary. The second practice (SEC2) did not diffuse despite its perceived utility and exposure. Similar to the motives of adoption, the reasons for non-adoption varied depending on the status of the subsidiary. For instance, a respondent stated: [Large subsidiaries] thought [SEC2] was interesting but they believed it would cost them more to adapt it to local needs than if they just develop their own model. I think it’s worth it that they try it but it would take a boost from [a senior executive] to see that happen. It’s not a matter of money. And another informant commented: Unless you show them how this will help them maximize their budget, [small subsidiaries] won’t spend time and money in trying to get [SEC2] working there. Otherwise, they will push back. If corporate folks ask cash-poor affiliates to run with it then they would say: sure, this looks interesting – just give us some more resources. We can’t blame them for that. They really have tight budgets. The last secondary practice (SEC3) focused on the vetting of the regional dimension of diffusion mechanisms. It showed that a practice that has been transferred successfully within a region did not get to travel to other regions for the absence of organizational structure that fosters cross-regional visibility. A Canadian respondent stated: SEC3 worked well in [Canada]. It is now used in the US and they are quite happy with it. I am pretty sure Japanese marketers will find it helpful as they have the 59 same challenges as in the US. If they knew about it, if they were part of EMAC region for example, they would take it and make it work there. Our current organization structure doesn’t allow for much interaction between us and Japan. Maybe we need a kind of matrix structure so that we get some formal face-to-face time with them? I don’t know but that would be nice. These three secondary practices helped check the boundary conditions of our initial findings. As expected, they did not diffuse because they did not have the benefit of the conditions of visibility and success that are stated in our hypotheses. While the study of multiple incidents does not pretend any statistical validation, it was important to understand the reasons for both successes and failures to reinforce the credibility of our findings. 2.5 Discussion and Conclusions In the present study, we explored the relationship between organizational isomorphism and practice diffusion with particular interest in the regional dimension of the phenomenon. We examined the dynamics of diffusion through three theoretical lenses – economic efficiency, social legitimacy, and political power. To this end, we conceptualized the MNE in three different ways. We first viewed it as a constellation of social spaces (Morgan, 2011) where legitimacy seeking is the dominant logic (Kogut & Zander, 2003). Then, we conceptualized it as an internal market (Birkinshaw, 1997) where subsidiaries exchange products and services based on economic rationality. Finally, we considered it as a political arena (Djelic & Quack, 2003) where subsidiaries pursue corporate attention (Bouquet & Birkinshaw, 2008) and global mandates (Birkinshaw, 1996). By applying multiple analytical templates to the same 60 phenomenon, we are able to analyze the motivations of different stakeholders and subsequently make several contributions to the existing literature. The three primary practices allowed us to generate five propositions suggesting that the role type of a subsidiary is instrumental to the adoption of its practices by sister subsidiaries. When it comes to the reasons for adoption, the role of the subsidiary is also instrumental since strategic subsidiaries tend to adopt practices for legitimacy reasons while nonstrategic subsidiaries would do so for efficiency reasons. Finally, the region to which a subsidiary belongs may also affect the chances of its practices to be adopted. We distinguished between organizational regions that reflect the way an MNE structures its subsidiaries into regional clusters, and geographic regions that are defined following publicly available classifications such as the World Bank’s. We found that the organizational regions facilitate the visibility of practices and hence the possibility that a sister subsidiary may be interested and initiate their transfer. On the other hand, geographic regions offer a relative institutional homogeneity and thus increase the likelihood of success of the transfers being initiated. As expected, the three secondary practices failed to diffuse, despite the fact that they had the potential to do so according to our informants, due to their lack of visibility through organizational structure and to the lack of institutional proximity between originator and possible recipient subsidiaries. The study makes a contribution to the international management literature by suggesting that there is a regional dimension to practice diffusion within MNEs. They uphold the relative institutional homogeneity that is generally assumed within geographic regions (Arregle et al., 2009; Rugman, 2003). More specifically, our 61 empirical exploration suggests that organizational regions (organization structure) help ensure visibility to local practices while geographic regions (geographic proximity) are critical to their successful transfer. Accordingly, they have complementary effects on the adoption of practices. Another key contribution of this paper resides in the use of isomorphic forces to analyze intra-organizational dynamics of practice diffusion. This provides empirical evidence of the link between intra-organizational isomorphism and practice diffusion that has long been assumed in the literature but never verified empirically (Boxenbaum & Jonsson, 2008). The fine-grained analysis of data helped untangle the mimetic, normative, and coercive forces of institutional isomorphism. The three pillars (Scott, 2008) are generally viewed in the literature as a homogenous set of forces instead of being considered separately. Our results identify several conditions under which these forces operate as independent factors. These findings have practical and research implications. From a practice perspective, managers involved in the deployment of corporate practices need to be aware of the different logics at play. In particular, individual actors have their respective interests, mobilize different rationalities accordingly, and expect different outcomes from the deployment, facilitation or adoption of a given practice. In fact, the set of analytical logics we considered (efficiency, legitimacy and power) may be helpful in analyzing the motives of various stakeholders in any change management initiative. From a theoretical standpoint, the corresponding analytical templates (economic efficiency, institutional legitimacy, and political power) may be repeated in other studies. It 62 provides a comprehensive framework for strategic and organizational analysis, especially in the pluralistic context of the MNE. The separate analysis of individual isomorphic forces may also be reproduced in future studies as more research is needed to understand how they interact as a set and under what kind of conditions one becomes more relevant than others. Scholars and practitioners alike should also find the regional dimension of practice transfer interesting as it helps explain the dynamics of diffusion beyond the traditional dyadic involving home and host countries. There are several ways our findings may be developed further. First, the same study design could be replicated in different organizational settings. We have chosen the industry, firm, subsidiary, and originator department in order to control for important industry and organizational effects that may influence the dynamics underlying diffusion mechanisms. For instance, it would be useful to investigate how a subsidiary’s position in the network (e.g. role, mandate, or weight) may affect its ability to export or import certain practices. Second, the leadership style of management at the originator subsidiary, recipient subsidiary and head office levels may determine the isomorphic forces being mobilized. In particular, leaders with certain personal characteristics may be inclined to be more coercive than others. Third, it is not quite clear how recipient subsidiaries actually trade off efficiency and legitimacy imperatives, especially when both are critical to their performance and survival. This may be specifically addressed in a future study. Fourth, we focused our analysis on one most dominant isomorphic force at a time. It would be useful to explore how these forces interplay when more than one is involved in the process. 63 Finally, one may consider the geographic aspects of the diffusion phenomenon. For instance, it would be useful to investigate when practices travel through informal organizational paths rather than formal hierarchical structures. It would also be interesting to explore practice diffusion in light of the current debate on the regional versus global nature of international strategy. The way the CIP practice, for instance, disseminated may indicate that there is a regional dimension to diffusion mechanisms. Similarly, subsidiaries based in developing markets may behave differently from those located in more advanced economies due essentially to differences in their institutional contexts. As mentioned earlier, the LRJ practice has been adopted by Latin American subsidiaries voluntarily. One may speculate that this may be due to the institutional characteristics of their home region. Another aspect of the regional phenomenon that could be explored further is the fit between organizational regions and geographic regions. In other words, does it make a difference when an MNE chooses to define its regions (organization structure) using different criteria than geographic proximity as Healthcare Global Inc. did with its EMAC region that included countries from Africa, Asia, Europe, and North America? To conclude, this article advances our understanding of the diffusion of local practices from a regional perspective. It explores the intricacies underlying intra-MNE relationships using multiple theoretical lenses. It also provides a compelling example of a fine-grained qualitative analysis that bridges multiple levels of analysis. While we focused our investigation on practices within a single firm, the careful selection of the overall research design and empirical setting suggests that the findings may generalize to other MNEs in various industries. 64 References Aguilera, R. V., Flores, R. G., & Vaaler, P. M. 2007. Is it all a matter of grouping? Examining the regional effect in global strategy research. In S. B. Tallman (Ed.), A new generation in international strategic management: 209–228. Cheltenham, UK ; Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Allison, G. T. 1971. Essence of decision: explaining the Cuban missile crisis. Boston: Little, Brown. Anand, N., Gardner, H. K., & Morris, T. 2007. Knowledge-based innovation: Emergence and embedding of new practice areas in management consulting firms. Academy of Management Journal, 50(2): 22. Argote, L., McEvily, B., & Reagans, R. 2003. Managing knowledge in organizations: An integrative framework and review of emerging themes. Management Science, 49(4): 571. Arregle, J.-l., Beamish, P. W., & Hébert, L. 2009. The regional dimension of MNEs' foreign subsidiary localization. Journal of International Business Studies, 40(1): 86. Bartlett, C. A., & Ghoshal, S. 1987. Managing Across Borders: New Strategic Requirements (Part 1). Sloan Management Review, 28(4): 7. Birkinshaw, J. 1996. How multinational subsidiary mandates are gained and lost. Journal of International Business Studies, 27(3): 467. Birkinshaw, J. 1997. Entrepreneurship in Multinational Corporations: The characteristics of subsidiary initiatives. Strategic Management Journal, 18(3): 207. Birkinshaw, J. 1999. The determinants and consequences of subsidiary initiative in multinational corporations. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 24(1): 9. Bouquet, C., & Birkinshaw, J. 2008. Weight versus voice: How foreign subsidiaries gain attention from corporate headquarters. Academy of Management Journal, 51(3): 577. Boxenbaum, E., & Jonsson, S. 2008. Isomorphism, diffusion and decoupling. In R. Greenwood (Ed.), The SAGE handbook of organizational institutionalism: xviii, 822 p. Los Angeles: Sage. Burgelman, R., A. 1983. A model of the interaction of the strategic behavior, corporate context, and the concept of strategic. The Academy of Management Review, 8(000001): 61. DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review(48): 14. Djelic, M.-L., & Quack, S. 2003. Governing globalization-bringing institutions back in. In M.-L. Djelic, & S. Quack (Eds.), Globalization and Institutions: Redefining the Rules of the Economic Game: 1-14. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Dubois, A., & Gadde, L.-E. 2002. Systematic combining: an abductive approach to case research. Journal of Business Research, 55(7): 553-560. Dunning, J. H., & Lundan, S. M. 2008. Multinational enterprises and the global economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. 65 Eisenhardt, K. M. 1989. Building Theories From Case Study Research. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 14(4): 532. Ghoshal, S., & Bartlett, C. A. 1988. Creation, adoption, and diffusion of innovations by subsidiaries. Journal of International Business Studies, 19(3): 365. Ghoshal, S., & Bartlett, C. A. 1990. The multinational corporation as an interorganizational network. Academy of Management Review, 15(4): 626. Glaser, B. G. 1998. Doing grounded theory: Issues and discussions. Mill Valley, Calif.: Sociology Press. Glaser, B. G., & Strauss, A. L. 1967. The discovery of grounded theory; strategies for qualitative research. New York: Aldine. Gupta, A. K., & Govindarajan, V. 1994. Organizing for knowledge flows within MNCs. International Business Review, 3(4): 443-457. Harris, S. G., & Sutton, R. I. 1986. Functions of Parting Ceremonies in Dying Organizations. Academy of Management Journal, 29(1): 5. Hedlund, G. 1986. The Hypermodern MNC -- A Heterarchy? Human Resource Management, 25(1): 9. Kennedy, M., & Fiss, P. 2009. Institutionalization, framing, and diffusion: The logic of TQM adoption and implementation decisions among U.S. hospitals. Academy of Management Journal, 52(5): 897. Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 2003. Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(6): 516. Kostova, T. 1996. Success of the transnational transfer of organizational practices within multinational companies. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis, University of Minnesota, USA. Kostova, T. 1999. Transnational transfer of strategic organizational practices: A contextual perspective. Academy of Management Review, 24(2): 308. Kostova, T., & Roth, K. 2002. Adoption of an organizational practice by subsidiaries of multinational corporations: Institutional and relational effects. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 215. Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. 1999. Organizational legitimacy under conditions of complexity: The case of the multinational enterprise. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 24(1): 64. Langley, A. 1999. Strategies for theorizing from process data. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 24(4): 691. Lawrence, T. B., Hardy, C., & Phillips, N. 2002. Institutional effects of interorganizational collaboration: The emergence of proto-institutions. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 281-290. Glynn, M. A., & Abzug, R. 2002. Institutionalizing Identity: Symbolic isomorphisms and organizational names. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 267-280. Meyer, A., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology: 83. Miles, M. B., & Huberman, A. M. 1994. Qualitative data analysis: An expanded sourcebook (2nd ed.). Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage. Minbaeva, D. B. 2007. Knowledge Transfer in Multinational Corporations. Management International Review, 47(4): 567. 66 Morgan, G. 2011. Reflections on the macro-politics of micro-politics. In C. Dörrenbächer, & M. Geppert (Eds.), Politics and Power in the Multinational Corporation: The Role of Institutions, Interests and Identities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Nachum, L., & Song, S. 2011. The MNE as a portfolio: Interdependencies in MNE growth trajectory. Journal of International Business Studies, 42: 24. Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Osegowitsch, T., & Sammartino, A. 2008. Reassessing (home-)regionalisation. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(2): 184-196. Peng, M., & Pleggenkuhle-Miles, E. 2009. Current debates in global strategy. International Journal of Management Reviews, 11(1): 51. Peng, M. W. 2002. Towards an Institution-Based View of Business Strategy. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 19(2/3): 251. Porter, M. E. 1986. Changing Patterns of International Competition. California Management Review, 28(2): 9. Pratt, M. G. 2009. From the editors: "For the Lack of a Boilerplate: Tips on Writing up (And Reviewing) Qualitative Research". Academy of Management Journal, 52(5 ): 856 - 862 Rosenzweig, P. M., & Singh, J. V. 1991. Organizational Environments and the Multinational Enterprise. Academy of Management Review, 16(2): 340. Roth, K. 1992. International Configuration and Coordination Archetypes for... Journal of International Business Studies, 23(3): 533. Rugman, A. M. 2003. The regional solution: Triad strategies for multinationals. Business Horizons, 46(6): 3. Rugman, A. M. 2005. The regional multinationals: MNEs and "global" strategic management. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Rugman, A. M., & Dossett, A. 2005. Wal-Mart and Carrefour as Home-Region Multinationals. European Retail Digest(48): 61-65. Santos, F. M., & Eisenhardt, K. M. 2009. Constructing markets and shaping boundaries: Entrepreneurial power in nascent fields. Academy of Management Journal, 52(4): 643. Scott, W. R. 2008. Institutions and organizations : ideas and interests (3rd ed.). Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage Publications. Szulanski, G., Jensen, R., & Lee, T. 2003. Adaptation of Know-how for Cross-border Transfer. Management International Review, 43(3): 131. Thornton, P. H., & Ocasio, W. 2008. Institutional Logics. In R. Greenwood (Ed.), The SAGE handbook of organizational institutionalism: xviii, 822 p. Los Angeles: Sage. Xu, D., & Shenkar, O. 2002. Institutional distance and the multinational enterprise. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 27(4): 608618. Yin, R. K. 2003. Case study research: Design and Methods (3rd ed.). Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications. Zaheer, S. 1995. Overcoming the liability of foreignness. Academy of Management Journal, 38(2): 341. 67 Appendices Table III – Characteristics of Practices STRATEGIC PRACTICE COUNTRY INTEGRATED PLAN (CIP) MARKET STRATEGIC LEADERSHIP (MSL) LOCAL RESEARCH JOURNAL (LRJ) GENERAL CHARACTERISTICS Description / Purpose Diffusion Reach Key Dates Full model intended to achieve cross-functional strategic alignment at the subsidiary level. All subsidiaries: Regional then Global Started in Canada: 2007 Deployed globally: 2009 Strategic relationship management model aimed at building lasting relationship with clients. Some strategic subsidiaries: EU, US, Asia Started in Canada: 2003 Large Recipient Sub.: 2007 Full model intended to provide scientific support to marketing and sales teams. Some small subsidiaries: Latin America Started in Canada: 2006 Small Recipient Sub.: 2008 DIFFUSION MECHANISMS Diffusion Support Process Type HQ Role Organization Path Organizational Structure Subsidiary Network Internal Market Mediated diffusion Mediator (quasi-owner) Moderated diffusion Moderator (facilitator) Lateral diffusion Observer (no direct role) HQ HQ OS RS OS OS HQ RS RS Selection Logic HQ mandated all subsidiaries to implement HQ RS HQ [OS RS] Self-selected large and strategic subsidiaries with HQ validation OS RS OS RS Self-selected subsidiaries with no HQ intervention ISOMORPHIC DYNAMICS Origin of Pressure Dominant Pressure Logic of Diffusion Headquarters RS-OS-HQ negotiation Recipient Subsidiary Mostly Coercive Power Mostly Normative Legitimacy Mostly Mimetic Efficiency THEORETICAL REPLICATION Secondary Practices (predictably different results) SEC1 is functionally similar to CIP, but it didn’t diffuse due to lack of visibility. It was developed by a non-strategic subsidiary that had no access to corporate forums to sell it. SEC2 was not adopted (despite claimed interest) because it did not offer sufficient legitimacy incentives to strategic subsidiaries or sufficient efficiency incentives to non-strategic subsidiaries. 68 㨁EC3 was not adopted for lack of visibility due in part to the organization structure that did not allow for interaction between Canadian and Japanese teams which would be supposedly interested. Figure 3 Tri-dimensional Transfer Flows of Organizational Practices within the MNE Head-office as Intermediary (HQ) Practice Cascading (top-down flows) Practice Escalation (bottom-up flows) Subsidiary as Originator (OS) Practice Borrowing (peer-to-peer flows) 69 Subsidiary as Recipient (RS) Chapter 3 – Location Choices by Multinational Enterprises from Emerging Markets: Legitimizing versus Economizing Logic4 Abstract This paper investigates the dominant logics underlying foreign location choices by multinational enterprises from emerging markets (EM-MNEs). The economic view of host country selection suggests that MNEs in general tend to focus their activities in nearby countries for efficiency reasons. In contrast, recent studies with institutional view posit that EM-MNEs in particular tend to prevail in developing markets for legitimacy imperatives. We mobilize and contrast economic efficiency and institutional legitimacy rationalities to study the logic underlying location choices by EM-MNEs. We analyze the configurations of the location networks of 203 EM-MNEs and show general empirical support for our theoretical predictions. In particular, EMMNEs are found to mobilize different logics depending on whether location choices are made within their home regions or elsewhere. Specifically, they follow economizing logic only in their home regions. In other regions, they seem to arbitrate legitimizing logic and economizing logic depending on the degree of their international experience. Our findings make important contributions to the current debates on the regional nature of international strategy and on the internationalization process of EM-MNEs. They also have important theoretical and managerial implications. Keywords Location choice, dominant logic, regional strategy, economic efficiency, institutional legitimacy, MNE Network configuration, multinationals from emerging markets, developing countries. An earlier version of this paper has been presented at the Strategic Management Society (2011) annual meeting. 4 3.1 Introduction In the present paper we examine geographic diversification patterns of multinational enterprises from emerging markets (EM-MNEs). For the benefit of simplicity, we use the term developing markets to identify the economies of all countries except those of developed countries as defined by the World Bank (2007). This includes firms from emerging, developing, and least-developed countries. We analyze the configurations of their location networks from the perspectives of economic efficiency and institutional legitimacy. One possible explication of international diversification patterns of MNEs in general is best illustrated by Rugman and colleagues (Rugman, 2005; Rugman & Verbeke, 2004b, 2005, 2007, 2008b) who suggested that MNEs tend to concentrate their activities in their home regions because they seek to maximize their Firm-Specific Advantages (FSA) in nearby markets (Rugman, 2005). Consistent with the principles of transaction cost economics, MNEs that focus geographically are likely to reduce their internationalization costs and exploit local linkages and externalities (Rugman & Verbeke, 2005). A key assumption underlying this reasoning is that the liability of foreignness of MNEs (Hymer, 1976) is lower in their home regions than elsewhere (Rugman & Verbeke, 2007). While relative institutional proximity is generally assumed within a region (Arregle, Beamish, & Hébert, 2009; Rugman, 2005), all regions are not necessarily homogeneous from an institutional perspective. Additionally, a country may be a member of several supranational groups of countries or regions with dissimilar levels of institutional development. An alternative rationalization of international diversification patterns is rooted in institutional legitimacy arguments. Zaheer (1995) suggested that liability of foreignness arises not only from the costs directly associated with geographic distance but also from the lack of social legitimacy, and that the two factors may not necessarily be related. Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc (2008) for instance suggested that EMMNEs prevail in least-developed countries (LDC) not because of geographic proximity but due to the fact that LDC’s institutional conditions are relatively similar to those of emerging markets where EM-MNEs have grown and learned how to deal with highly informal institutions (Dunning & Lundan, 2008; Hyman, 1993; Jütting, Drechsler, Bartsch, & de Soysa, 2007). Peripheral countries like Mexico provide tangible examples of the tension that exists between the needs for both economic opportunity and institutional proximity. As a member of NAFTA and a neighbour of the US and Canada, Mexican MNEs have economic incentives to trade with the large American and Canadian markets. On the other hand, Mexican institutions are much more similar to those of remote Argentina (colonial heritage, developing country, common language) than to those of the neighbouring US or Canada (geographic proximity, NAFTA economic incentive). The unravelling of this tension may help explain the reasons why MNEs in general venture into geographically distant countries before they maximize their presence in their home regions (Peng & Pleggenkuhle-Miles, 2009) and why EM-MNEs in particular seem to be neither path dependent nor evolutionary in selecting their foreign locations (Luo & Tung, 2007). The two perspectives provide complementary rather than contradictory explanations of location choices. While geographic relatedness is rooted in economic efficiency and economies of scope across borders, institutional relatedness is built upon institutional legitimacy and the exploitation of social capital across similar institutional settings. 72 Accordingly, the purpose of this paper is to investigate how economic logic and institutional logic interact to shape location choices by EM-MNEs and thus explain the configuration of their location networks. In attending to this enquiry, we organize the remaining parts of the paper as follows. First, we further discuss the concept of geographic diversification and develop hypotheses in relation to the logics underlying location choices. Then, we test our hypotheses, interpret the results, and discuss their research and practical implications. We conclude with the limitations of our study and possible avenues for future research. 3.2 Theoretical Foundations and Predictions Foreign location choice is a major consideration in the international strategy of MNEs (Dunning, 1998, 2000; Mudambi, 2002), and intra-firm linkages are key determinants of their arbitration (Chen & Chen, 1998). Consequently, these choices must be viewed as a portfolio of decisions rather than isolated choices. While most studies focused on individual locations as their unit of analysis in the past, some recent publications approached the phenomenon from a broader geographic scope. For instance, Rugman et al. (2004a) highlighted the tendency of MNEs to concentrate their sales and assets in their home regions, Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc (2008) underlined the prevalence of EM-MNEs in LDC markets, and Arregle et al. (2009) found that MNEs arbitrate location choices within their home regions. In order to have a holistic appreciation of their internationalization patterns, we conceptualize MNEs as inter-organizational networks of subsidiaries (Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1990) and investigate how member locations relate to each other. 73 3.2.1 Relatedness of Location Networks: Geography versus Institutions Business relatedness has been described as similarities among organizational units along central dimensions (Pehrsson, 2006; Stimpert & Duhaime, 1997). For instance, Peng et al. (2005:2) defined institutional relatedness as the “degree of [its] informal embeddedness or interconnectedness with [local] dominant institutions.” Following the same logic, we generalize and define the location relatedness of an MNE as the degree to which its network of subsidiaries is relatively integrated and homogeneous. While such integration and homogeneity may be assessed in various ways (Ghemawat, 2001), this study focuses on two dimensions – geography and institutions. From a geographic perspective, individual location choices may be explained by using Dunning's (2001) OLI framework which is also known as "eclectic paradigm". According to the model, host country decisions are driven by a combination of ownership, location, and internalization advantages. Ownership advantages are firmspecific (FSA), location advantages are country-specific (CSA), and internalization advantages derive from reducing or eliminating transaction costs of outsourcing activities by setting up a subsidiary in, rather than exporting to, a foreign country, for instance. As a complementary set of conditions, the three types of advantages shape location choices. Nevertheless, location-specific advantages are direct drivers of arbitration while ownership and internalization advantages provide secondary arguments to particular location choices (Mudambi, 2002). The primacy of location-specific advantages is illustrated by the spatial clustering of firms; a subject that has long been the focus of researchers in economic geography 74 (See Krugman, 1995 for an extented literature review). Specifically, location decisions may be guided by geographic proximity to facilitate the exploitation of linkages and externalities such as technological spillovers, skilled labour, and industry-specific input across the industry. At the organizational level, geographic proximity is also instrumental to location arbitration (Arregle et al., 2009). For instance, Rugman and colleagues (Rugman, 2005; Rugman & Verbeke, 2004b, 2005, 2007, 2008b) found that the largest MNEs from the extended Triad regions (Asia-Pacific, European Union, and NAFTA) tend to focus their sales and assets in their home regions. This is essentially the consequence of firms trying to combine the three types of specific advantages underlying OLI components. [E]ach foreign location requires location-specific linking investments to meld existing FSAs with CSAs. It is, ceteris paribus, the extent of these adaptation costs, taking into account the redeployability of the resulting additional knowledge in the relevant locations, that explains why most MNEs expand first in their home region, and may face great difficulty expanding to other regions. (Rugman & Verbeke, 2008a:13) The regional nature of international strategies is likely driven by the willingness of MNEs to structure their foreign subsidiary networks in such a way to optimize transaction costs (Rugman & Verbeke, 2005) and thus boost performance (Banalieva & Eddleston, 2011). Within their home regions, MNEs can combine their FSAs with CSA more easily and efficiently (Rugman, 2003) while reducing the costs associated with monitoring subsidiaries that are located in geographically distant countries (Chu-Chia & Ivan, 2003). The underlying transaction cost argument is particularly relevant to EM-MNEs because they are relatively smaller in size and poorer in 75 resources than DM-MNEs (Brouthers, O'Donnell, & Hadjimarcou, 2005). Thus, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1a (H1a): Overall, EM-MNEs will focus their activities in their home regions. A key assumption underlying the economic efficiency perspective is that regions are relatively homogeneous from an institutional perspective. For instance, Rugman & Verbeke (2005:3) defined the region as a “limited number of participants that are geographically close, and with a comparatively low economic and institutional distance among them." While the validity of the institutional homogeneity assumption is contingent upon the way the region itself is defined (Peng & Pleggenkuhle-Miles, 2009), there is a need to take institutional forces into account in a more direct way. In fact, location choices are motivated by social capital rather than economic opportunity. Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc (Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008) for instance explained the prevalence of EM-MNEs in least-developed countries (LDC) by their social ability to function in the peculiar institutional and economic conditions of LDC markets. Despite being smaller, having less sophisticated resources and coming from problematic home markets with poorly developed governance environments, developing-country MNEs can still be successful in their internationalization. The ability to manage in a challenging governance environment, which they have developed at home, can help them become leading firms in LDCs by reducing their difficulties in internationalization. (Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008:20) 76 One of the distinctive features of developing countries is the relatively high degree of informality in social, economic and political interactions among local actors (de Soysa & Jütting, 2007). This provides home-grown firms with a double competitive edge over their counterparts from more advanced economies (Taleb, 2010). First, informal settings act as incubator for EM-MNEs to learn how to mitigate or even take advantage of such conditions (Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008). Second, high informality serves as a psychological barrier of entry that prevents DM-MNEs from entering emerging markets and thus reduces pressure on local firms. Therefore, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 1b (H1b): Overall, EM-MNEs will focus their activities in emerging markets. Hypothesis 1a suggests that EM-MNE Networks are likely to be geographically integrated around the head office (geographic relatedness) while hypothesis 1b implies that EM-MNE Networks are likely to be institutionally homogenous (institutional relatedness). However, the two views are not mutually exclusive as both conditions may be fulfilled concurrently especially within the home regions of MNEs. 3.2.2 The Logics of Location Arbitrage: Economizing versus Legitimizing Relatedness of location networks implies some sort of consistency in location choices over time and space. Thus, a systematic analysis of the patterns of location choices by a particular MNE is likely to unveil a dominant logic (Bettis & Prahalad, 1995) because “generic strategy of diversification (how much and what kind of relatedness) is the key to achieving performance” (Prahalad & Bettis, 1986:2). The dominant managerial logics underlying the two types of location relatedness we discussed above are 77 economizing logic for geographic relatedness and legitimizing logic for institutional relatedness. For the purpose of this study, an EM-MNE is considered to follow a legitimizing logic when its location choices are predominantly driven by institutional proximity. As a result, MNEs that follow such logic will possess location networks with a relatively high institutional homogeneity. In contrast, EM-MNEs are said to follow an economizing logic when their location choices are essentially guided by market potential rather than by institutional proximity. Therefore, EM-MNEs that adopt this logic will have location networks with relatively high geographic concentration. From an EM-MNE perspective, economizing and economizing logics have complementary and divergent effects on location choices globally. This is because institutional proximity is not necessarily correlated with economic opportunity. Thus, EM-MNEs may not be familiar with the institutional settings of the markets that are most interesting from an economic perspective. However, as posited in hypotheses 1a and 1b, EM-MNEs tend to venture into markets with relatively worse or similar institutional conditions than the ones they are used to in their home countries. In other words, EM-MNEs following a legitimizing logic in location selection will start with developing markets where they can secure the highest level of legitimacy and end with industrialized economies where they face significant liability of foreignness. More formally, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 2a (H2a): Globally, the relationship between legitimizing logic and the geographic prevalence of an EM-MNE will be linear and negative. 78 We use the term “geographic prevalence” to indicate whether the majority of an MNE’s subsidiaries are located in advanced economies or in developing markets. The ratio will be positive when the majority is in advanced markets. In the same vein, cognitive bias of decision makers has been found to play an important role in entry decisions of EM-MNEs to developed markets (Thomas, Eden, Hitt, & Miller, 2007). Indeed, the psychic distance paradox (O Grady & Lane, 1996) means that managers assume similarity between countries erroneously when they make cross-border decisions (Evans & Mavondo, 2002). Therefore, consistent with Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc’s (2008) findings, EM-MNEs will tend to choose emerging markets over more advanced markets with higher economic opportunity potential. Location arbitration based on economizing logic is likely to first focus on a pool of countries with both low institutional maturity and high economic opportunities until it fades. Then, they will be forced to either take more institutional risks or reconsider their appetite for highest economic opportunities. Since EM-MNEs face the liability of foreignness when they get into unfamiliar markets, they are likely to seek more institutional legitimacy than economic opportunity until they get acquainted with new institutional contexts. As they gain confidence in operating in such settings, the number of options for location choices will increase. Accordingly, they will arbitrate location choices based on economic potential again. Hence, we hypothesize: Hypothesis 2b (H2b): Globally, the relationship between the geographic prevalence of an EM-MNE and economizing logic has a U-shape form. MNEs arbitrate location choices within regions (Arregle et al., 2009) because competitive advantages and liabilities of foreignness are regional in nature (Rugman & Verbeke, 2007). Given the relative institutional homogeneity inside regions (Arregle 79 et al., 2009; Rugman & Verbeke, 2007, 2008c), MNEs have incentives to use a single logic (Prahalad & Bettis, 1986) when they make location choices within their home regions. Whether institutional homogeneity is genuine or assumed (Asmussen, 2009), decision makers are likely to take relative institutional proximity for granted and thus focus on economic maximization in their home regions. While location choices are primarily driven by economizing logic within a home region, no two countries may be considered identical from an institutional point of view. Even minor institutional differences may still matter and the degree of international experience of an MNE will play an important role in how serious such differences may be perceived. For the same reasons we have discussed to justify the U-shape relationship between economizing logic and geographic prevalence at the global level, we hypothesize the following for a home region: Hypothesis 3 (H3): In the home region of an EM-MNE, its geographic prevalence has a U-shaped relationship with economizing logic. On the other hand, venturing into other regions may carry additional institutional risks because the ability of leadership to “manage a diversified firm is limited by the dominant general management logic(s) that they are used to” (Prahalad & Bettis, 1986:497). Operating in several regions may require the simultaneous mobilization of multiple logics (Prahalad & Bettis, 1986) to handle institutional heterogeneity and complexity. This is why both economizing and legitimizing logics are likely to entwine in host regions as they do globally. For the same reasons discussed at the global level, we expect the relationships between location choice logics and geographic prevalence in host regions to be similar to the ones we hypothesized worldwide: 80 Hypothesis 4a (H4a): In host regions, the relationship between legitimizing logic and the geographic prevalence of an EM-MNE will be linear and negative. Hypothesis 4b (H4b): In host regions, the relationship between the geographic prevalence of an EM-MNE and economizing logic has a U-shape form. The diversity of both economic and institutional conditions among countries in host regions represents a significant challenge for EM-MNEs in terms of organizational learning. Failure to understand the institutional conditions in unfamiliar markets may be costly (Orr & Scott, 2008), but the associated overhead is expected to decline as firms gain experience (Belderbos, Van Olffen, & Zou, 2011; Lu & Beamish, 2001; Zaheer, 1995). Therefore, the degree of an MNE's degree of internationalization (DOI) is likely to influence which of the economizing and legitimizing logics it will choose to adopt in host regions. 3.2.3 Moderating Effects of the International Experience in Host Regions An MNE's degree of internationalization affects its location choices (e.g., Buckley, Devinney, & Louviere, 2007). The Uppsala Stage Model (Johanson & Vahlne, 1977) underlined the incremental nature of an MNE's commitment to foreign markets. While the time factor is intrinsic to any organizational learning process, the depth and breadth of the required learning is essentially determined by the magnitude of differences and similarities between home and host countries from both economic and institutional perspectives. Firms with low international experience typically suffer higher liability of foreignness in unknown regions in comparison to those with relatively higher experience. They are more likely to follow legitimizing logic rather than economizing logic when they 81 venture into unknown markets in host regions. As they acquire more experience, they are likely to show "less preference for near, similar and familiar markets" (Buckley et al., 2007:3). As a result, legitimizing logic, which is aimed at mitigating the liability of foreignness, is likely to weaken and economizing logic, which is aimed at maximizing economic opportunities, is anticipated to strengthen. In other words, the relationships we hypothesized for host regions will be moderated by the degree of experience of the EM-MNE. Specifically, it will strengthen the effects of the U-shaped relationship (H4a) and will weaken the effect of the invested U-shaped relationship (H4b). Hence, we submit: Hypothesis 5a (H5a): In host regions, the effect of legitimizing logic on the geographic prevalence of EM-MNEs will be weaker with an increasing degree of their internationalization. Hypothesis 5b (H5b): In host regions, the effect of economizing logic on the geographic prevalence of EM-MNEs will be stronger with an increasing degree of their internationalization. 3.3 Research Methods 3.3.1 Data Sample Given the nature of our study, we have chosen to focus on MNEs from developing and emerging markets (EM-MNEs). The main reason is because the economic and institutional characteristics of their home countries allow for a better distinction between economizing and legitimizing behaviour than those of more developed markets (DM-MNEs). It would be more difficult to infer from publicly available data 82 which of institutional proximity and economic opportunity logic explains location choices by DM-MNEs. This is because, from a DM-MNE perspective, developed markets are both institutionally proximate and economically attractive. On the contrary, EM-MNEs need to arbitrate between institutional similarities with emerging markets and economic opportunities generally found in more developed markets. We use a proprietary database to test the hypotheses. The original dataset was compiled from several reliable sources: BvD ORBIS database, LexisNexis Academic database, and publicly available data to complement them. First, we used Orbis database (2010) and followed a similar approach to the ones used by UNCTAD (2008) and Fortune Global 500 (2009) to identify the world's largest EM-MNEs. Our approach is guided by the availability and reliability of data, along the lines of recent studies that examined the internationalization patterns of EM-MNEs (e.g., Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008). The sample is also conveniently diverse from both geographic and institutional perspectives, which makes it particularly suitable for the testing of our hypotheses. Given the large size of these MNEs, they are located in several countries, in home and host regions, which is instrumental to the exploration of the dominant logics underlying the patterns of their location choices (Arregle, Hébert, & Beamish, 2006). Second, we used ownership structures in LexisNexis (2009) and Orbis Ownership (2010) databases to reconstruct the location networks of individual MNEs. In line with the existing International Business (IB) literature, subsidiaries are defined as those in which the head office holds at least a 50.1% of ownership (e.g., Arregle et al., 2009). Finally, when the relevant data were not available in Orbis Ownership and LexisNexis databases, or when we were uncertain about their reliability, we searched other sources such as D&B Who Owns Whom catalogues (2009) and the annual reports of companies. After discarding the firms with insufficient, unreliable or 83 uncertain data from an original dataset of 500 EM-MNEs, the final sample included 203 firms from 24 different countries. -----------------------------------Insert Table IV about here. -----------------------------------3.3.2 Variables and Measures The unit of analysis is the MNE Network. For each MNE, we identified all majorityowned subsidiaries global and grouped them by countries and regions using the World Bank’s classification (2007). Table V provides detailed information about the measurement and data sources for all variables. -----------------------------------Insert Table V about here. -----------------------------------Dependent variable Geographic Prevalence (GP) is the dependent variable in our model. It indicates whether an MNE’s locations are predominantly based in emerging markets or in developed markets. We followed a similar approach to the one used by CuervoCazurra & Genc (2008) to compute this variable: GP = DM # SUB − EM # SUB TOT # SUB where DM#SUB is the number of the MNE's subsidiaries that are based in developed markets; EM#SUB is the number of the MNE’s subsidiaries that are located in emerging markets; and TOT#SUB is the total number of the MNE’s subsidiaries worldwide. Therefore, a positive ratio would mean that the MNE prevails in developed markets whereas a negative ratio would indicate that the majority of the MNE’s locations are based in emerging markets. 84 Independent variables The model includes two independent variables: Institutional Distance Index (IDI) and Economic Distance Index (EDI). They are aggregate values of two widely used measures but at the MNE Network level: institutional distance and economic distance. On the one hand, IDI is a proxy for Legitimizing Logic and informs on the magnitude of relatedness among the locations that form the MNE Network from an institutional distance standpoint (e.g., Kostova & Zaheer, 1999; Xu & Shenkar, 2002). On the other hand, EDI is a proxy Economizing Logic and indicates the magnitude of relatedness among the locations that constitute the MNE Network from an economic distance point of view (e.g., Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008; Ghemawat, 2001). Conceptually, IDI and EDI may be likened to a centre of gravity of the MNE from institutional and economic perspectives. They essentially convey the nature of the dominant logic underlying a given MNE Network configuration. To calculate IDI, we used the World Bank’s governance indicators (Kaufmann, Kraay, & Mastruzzi, 2009) that reflect the quality of national governance systems: voice and accountability, political stability and absence of violence, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of corruption. These governance indicators have been used in country-level comparative studies (e.g., Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008) because they reflect the quality of national institutions. Governance consists of the traditions and institutions by which authority in a country is exercised. This includes the process by which governments are selected, monitored and replaced; the capacity of the government to effectively formulate and implement sound policies; and the respect of citizens and the state for the institutions that govern economic and social interactions among them. (Kaufmann et al., 2009:5) 85 For the purpose of this study, we are interested in measuring the average institutional distance (IDI) between the home country of individual MNEs and the host countries of their foreign subsidiaries. It is computed in two steps. The first step consisted of calculating a 10-year average (1999-2008) for each governance indicator. We have chosen 10-year average because (i) that is the period for which the data is available, (ii) institutional conditions are relatively stable over time and even dramatic changes in public policy would take some time before they affect governance indicators, and (iii) recent studies showed that a 10-year period is relatively sufficient to capture the essence of ongoing location arbitrage within regions (Arregle et al., 2009), thereby reflecting the dominant logics behind MNE Network configurations. The second step consisted in averaging institutional distances between the head office and individual locations to obtain a single score for each MNE. To sum up, the degree of an MNE's legitimizing logic (IDI) is computed as follows: IDI = 1 n 1 6 ∑ ∑ GovInd [d] (HQ) - GovInd [d] (SUB[s]) n s =1 d d =1 where IDI is the mean of differences between the score of the dth governance dimension of the head office's home country and those of the host countries of all subsidiaries forming the MNE network; n is the total number of majority-owned subsidiaries in the MNE Network; GovInd [d] (HQ) is the dth governance indictor of the MNE’s home country, and GovInd [d](SUB[s]) is the dth governance indicator (1 to 6) of the country hosting the sth subsidiary. On the other hand, EDI reflects the logic of economic opportunity underlying an MNE Network of locations. In International Business literature, foreign direct investments and location choices have long been associated with economic distance (ED) between 86 home and host countries (Ghemawat, 2001). It has generally been measured in terms of market size or market growth (Berry, Guillen, & Zhou, 2010). The largest markets are typically located in developed countries and EM-MNEs are known to prevail in least-developed and developing countries (Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008). As a consequence, EM-MNEs are more likely to favour market growth over market size when it comes to assessing economic opportunities. For this reason, we use annual GDP growth rate rather than market size to measure economic distance between home and host countries. The degree of the economizing logic of an MNE is reflected by its EDI, which is calculated as follows: EDI = 1 n ∑ GDPGrowth (HQ) - GDPGrowth (SUB[s]) n s =1 where n is the number of countries in which the MNE has majority-owned subsidiaries, GDPGrowth (HQ) is the 10-year average growth of MNE's home country between 1999 and 2008, GDPGrowth (SUB[s]) is the 10-year average growth rate (1999-2008) in the host country of subsidiary s. Control variables Several variables have been found in the IB literature to influence location choices. Five of them are particularly relevant to the particular phenomenon under study. At the firm level, size, age, industry, and degree of international experience play a critical role. At the country level, FDI potential between home and host countries is of interest as well. Firm size is a key determinant of foreign direct investments because large MNEs have access to more resources and capabilities than smaller one (Yiu, ChungMing, & Bruton, 87 2007). Consistent with prior studies, we use the natural logarithm of total sales rather than assets due to data availability. Firm age has been found to influence the ability of a firm to internationalize because of the experience and knowledge it can accumulate over time. It is measured using the natural logarithm of the number of years between our year of reference (2009) and the firm’s inception date. Industry is also included as a control variable to ensure that its effects are taken into account. We used the American SIC classification to code this variable (CuervoCazurra & Genc, 2008). Degree of internationalization (DOI) reflects the experience of an MNE in foreign economic and institutional settings. It is generally approached in terms of scale or scope of the MNE's activities. The scale (or depth) of internationalization is generally measured using sales, assets, or number of employees (e.g., Lu & Beamish, 2001; Rugman, 2005; Rugman & Oh, 2009), whereas the scope (or breath) of internationalization is generally measured in terms of the number of foreign subsidiaries or the number of countries in which an MNE is located (e.g., CuervoCazurra & Genc, 2008; Rugman & Oh, 2009; Tallman & Li, 1996). This study is concerned with the breadth of internationalization, and so we measure the degree of internationalization using the ratio of foreign-to-total number of subsidiaries. By using the number of subsidiaries rather than the number of countries (Hitt, Hoskisson, & Kim, 1997) we factor in the weights of individual countries in the composition of MNE Networks. 88 FDI potential between two countries has also been at the centre of international economics and foreign direct investments. As discussed earlier, the potential of bilateral trade and FDI can be measured in terms of market size or market growth (Berry et al., 2010). Since we used market growth to measure the independent variable EDI, we opt for market size to measure bilateral FDI potential. To measure the effect of market size, we follow the gravity model that is generally used to explicate not only bilateral trade but also FDI flows (Li & Vashchilko, 2010). Accordingly, the GDP per capita of the home country is multiplied by the GDP per capita of the host country and the product is divided by the geographic distance between the two nations. Similar to the operationalization approach of geographic distance by Bouquet & Birkinshaw (2008), we obtained data from the CEPII's distance database (Mayer & Zignago, 2011). It used the Great Circle formula which computes geographic distance between two countries using the latitude and longitude coordinates of the most populous cities in these countries (Mayer & Zignago, 2011). Home Region is used to check whether the localization (or not) of subsidiaries in the home region of their parent's home country affects the logic of location choices. This is important because international strategies are posited to be rather regional in nature (Rugman & Verbeke, 2007). 3.4 Analyses Since the phenomenon we study spans several organizational and geographic levels, we verified the relevance of adopting a multilevel analysis approach. Specifically, we used HLM 6.07 to check for independent effects at the local, regional, and global levels. The analysis shows that level 3 Intraclass Correlation Coefficient (ICC) is below the threshold of .10 which means that less than 10% of the variability in a location choice 89 could be explained by, or is related to, variables at the MNE's home country level. This suggests that multilevel analysis is not relevant or particularly indicated for this study (Beretvas, 2007; Bliese, 2000). Therefore, we used simple regression under STATA 9.1 to test hypotheses. We verified the relationships between alternative logics and geographic prevalence using the following model: Geographic Prevalence = β0 + β1 Ln(Size) + β2 Ln(Age) + β3 Degree of Internationalization + β4 Ln(FDI Potential) + β5 Industry + β6 Institutional Distance Index + β7 Economic Distance Index + β8 DOIxIDI + β9 DOIxEDI + ε The hypotheses are considered supported when the coefficient of β6 and β8 are negative (liability) and statistically significant, and the coefficients of β7 and Β9 are positive (advantages) and statistically significant. Table VI provides the general descriptive statics and correlations of the variables in the model. -----------------------------------Insert Table VI about here. -----------------------------------Table IV shows how the whole locations of the 203 EM-MNEs in our sample are distributed geographically by comparing data of the home region and host region, on the one hand; and those of developing markets and developed markets on the other hand. -----------------------------------Insert Table VII about here. -----------------------------------These statistics indicate that subsidiaries are predominantly located within the home regions of their parents (59%) and in emerging markets (62%). These findings offer support for hypotheses H1a and H1b. 90 In Table VIII, we show the results of our statistical analysis. Model 1 is used as a baseline with control variables only. There is a baseline for each geographic grouping of locations we analyze separately: worldwide, home regions, and host regions. Model 2 incorporates two additional variables, namely IDI and EDI, which are proxies for legitimizing logic and economizing logic allowing for the testing of Hypothesis 2. The results provide support for H2a, since the coefficient of IDI is negative and statistically significant (-52.96 [p<0.05]) and its quadratic term is statistically non-significant which indicates that the relationship is linear in nature. They are also supportive of H2b given that the coefficient of EDI is positive and statistically significant (12.13 [p<0.05]) and its quadratic term is positive and statistically significant. This implies that the relationship between EDI and geographic prevalence has a U-shape form. Finally, this model shows that both legitimizing and economizing logics have significantly different effects on geographic prevalence, depending on whether a subsidiary belongs to the same region as its parent or not (23.08 [p<0.05] and 6.11 [p<0.05] respectively). ------------------------------------Insert Table VIII about here. ------------------------------------Model 3 and Model 4 provide the testing outcomes for Hypotheses 3 and 4, which suggest that location decisions by EM-MNEs follow distinct logics depending on whether choices are made within or outside of their home regions. The results presented in Model 3 support the suggestion that location choices are driven by economizing logic only in home regions. The tests show that IDI is non-significant while the coefficient of EDI is positive and statistically significant (7.79 [p<0.05]). Furthermore, the quadratic term of EDI is positive and statistically significant, which implies that the relationship between economizing logic and geographic prevalence in 91 home regions follows a U-shape trend. This is in line with the regional view of international strategy which assumes a relative homogeneity of institutional conditions within home regions (Rugman & Sukpanich, 2006). On the other hand, Model 4 pertains to location choices out of home regions. The results show that the coefficient of IDI is negative and significant (-34.56 [p<0.05]) and that of EDI is positive and statistically significant (6.04 [p<0.05]). In addition, the quadratic term of EDI is positive and statistically significant. These results support H4a, which predicted a linear negative relationship between IDI and geographic prevalence, and H4b, which posited a U-shape relationship between EDI and geographic prevalence. These findings for host regions are fully consistent with existing theories as they emphasize the importance of both economic and institutional distances in international context (Ghemawat, 2001) including when it comes to location choice decisions (Belderbos et al., 2011). In order to unravel the intertwined effects of the legitimizing and economizing logics in host regions, we have tested for interactions between the legitimizing logic and the degree of internationalization (Hypothesis H5a) and between the economizing logic and the degree of internationalization (Hypothesis H5b). Model 5 provides the results of our statistical analysis showing support for H5b and confirms that the degree of internationalization moderates the relationship between economizing logic and geographic prevalence (0.02 [p<0.05]). That is, the tendency of EM-MNEs to seek economic opportunities in host regions will increase in the early stages of their international expansion and decrease as they gain experience. This is probably due to the fact that firms are likely to find a pool of countries with relatively lower or similar institutional conditions they can choose from when they start venturing outside of their home region. By selecting one of these countries, they reduce the levels of institutional uncertainty and hence their liability of foreignness in 92 the chosen country. Consequently, economizing logic will be the dominant driver of location arbitration in the early stage of internationalization. As the number of options will diminish over time, this will entail either taking more institutional risk or lessening their appetite for high economic opportunities. Given the tendency of EMMNEs to prevail in developing and emerging markets, they are expected to ease their economic appetite rather than increase their institutional risk. This is consistent with our findings that the degree of experience does not moderate the linear relationship between legitimizing logic and geographic prevalence as hypothesized in H5a. Furthermore, we focus on EM-MNEs which tend to concentrate their activities in home regions and emerging markets. A large majority of home countries of the firms in our sample (Table IV) are among the most mature emerging markets from an institutional perspective. Therefore, they have the advantage of being able to understanding other emerging markets as well as more advanced economies. As a result, legitimacy building is indeed required as suggested by the statistical significance of IDI in host regions (-34.59 [p<0.05]), but the learning process is relatively linear and incremental over time. --------------------------------------Insert Figure 4 about here. --------------------------------------More specifically, Figure 4 shows that the degree of international experience moderates the relationship between EDI and geographic prevalence only when the economic growth rate of the host country is higher than the growth rate of the home country’s economy (negative EDI). In other words, the higher the geographic prevalence ratio of an MNE, the higher its need for international experience. This is comprehensible since high geographic prevalence ratio implies more developed markets than developing markets in the MNE portfolio of locations. We suggest that 93 when an EM-MNE choosing between a developed market and an emerging market of the same market growth rate, it will likely choose the emerging market for institutional proximity reasons unless it already has significant international experience. 3.5 Discussion In line with the existing literature, we found that the activities of EM-MNEs prevail in their home regions on the one hand, and in emerging markets on the other hand. We subsequently used a cross-sectional dataset to examine whether EM-MNEs follow distinct logics when they choose their foreign locations within and outside of their home regions. Our findings confirm that EM-MNEs arbitrate the need for institutional legitimacy and the search for economic opportunity differently depending on whether location choices take place within their home regions or not. The results of our statistical analysis are supportive of our predictions that EM-MNEs follow economizing logic in their home regions and a mix of legitimizing and economizing logics in remote regions. This empirical investigation of the dominant logics underlying location choices by EMMNEs contributes to strategic management and international business literature in several ways. First, we take a holistic approach to the examination of the MNE's behaviour rather than focusing on individual host country choices. We conceptualize the MNE as a network of locations and view the underlying choices as a portfolio of decisions reflecting strategies that emerge and crystallize over time (Mintzberg & Waters, 1985). This approach represents a significant departure from the traditional dyadic view of localization based on the matching of home and host countries. 94 Second, we identified the dominant logics (Bettis & Prahalad, 1995; Prahalad & Bettis, 1986) underlying the overall pattern of decisions by analyzing the configurations of location networks. We draw upon international business literature to suggest two alternative logics of location selection: economic efficiency and institutional legitimacy. While scholars emphasized the importance of considering both economic and institutional factors in explaining strategic decisions in the past (Peng, 2002), this study goes beyond complementarity. We contrasted the two logics and suggested that one may matter more than the other depending on organizational factors and geographic settings. Third, the fact that EM-MNEs mobilize different logics of location selection when they venture out of their home regions substantiates the importance of studying the regional dimension of cross-border phenomena in international business (Rugman & Verbeke, 2004b). While home regions are not necessarily institutionally homogeneous, they are generally assumed by decision makers to be so. This home region bias is perhaps the reason why the logic of location arbitration within home region is driven by economic opportunity rather than by institutional familiarity. Consequently, the degree of the internationalization was found to influence the nature of the relationship between economizing logic and geographic prevalence in host regions, but has no statistically significant effect on the relationship between legitimizing logic and geographic prevalence. Finally, this study provides a tangible example of phenomena that are better investigated using data on EM-MNEs rather than DM-MNEs. As their markets mature and institutions formalize, emerging countries represent a fantastic laboratory not only for the replication of existing theories but also for the development of new ones 95 (Taleb, 2010). It would be particularly complex to ascertain from publicly available data whether a DM-MNE entering a developed market is driven by economizing logic or legitimizing logic. This is because the tension between institutional imperatives and economic needs would be lower for a DM-MNE than for an EM-MNE. That is, economic opportunity and institutional familiarity are likely to correlate for DM-MNEs and diverge for EM-MNEs due to the characteristics of their home countries. This also underlines the fact that the natures of the trade-offs EM-MNEs and DM-MNEs need to make when they arbitrate location choices are relatively different. The findings of this study have important theoretical and practical implications. From a research perspective, the conceptualization of location choices as a portfolio of decisions and the identification of the dominant logics underlying MNE Network configurations provide a holistic approach to the analysis of firm behaviour as opposed to individual decisions. A few recent studies opted for a similar perspective (e.g., Nachum & Song, 2011) and more scholars interested in international business, strategic management, and organizational theories may find this approach useful in conducting future studies. Furthermore, the fact that legitimizing and economizing logics interact within and outside home regions in different ways helps contextualize the decisions of MNEs. In particular, it reiterates the need for scholars to pay particular attention to the regional dimension of the firm’s international action. Finally, the focus on EM-MNEs helps one to understand the behaviour of an increasingly influential group of multinational firms. From a management practice view, decision makers may find it helpful to think about their own strategies as well as those of their competitors from a dominant logic perspective. In particular, managers who seek to anticipate the strategic moves of 96 their competitors will appreciate the predictive power of this concept because it assumes relative consistency in behaviour over time. While the idea of dominant logic may not be new to practitioners, this study provides a tangible example of its usefulness in concrete strategic analysis. By shedding some light on the mechanisms of location arbitration that has been found in the past to be regional in nature (Arregle et al., 2009), it increases the awareness of senior managers about the regional logics of strategic decision-making. In particular, decision makers should expect their competitors to possibly change managerial logics, especially when they venture outside their home regions. 3.6 Conclusion The objective of this paper is to explore the logics underlying foreign location choices by MNEs from emerging and developing markets. We began by asking how EM-MNEs arbitrate economic aspirations and institutional contingencies when they choose the locations of their foreign subsidiaries. Drawing upon transaction cost economics and new institutional theories, we generated nine hypotheses and tested them using a dataset of 203 MNEs from emerging markets. As discussed earlier, the focus on this category of MNEs is particularly helpful in disentangling the competing – economizing and legitimizing – logics, which would be difficult to achieve otherwise with a population of MNEs from more advanced economies. We conceptualized the MNE as a network of subsidiaries and the underlying location choices as a portfolio of decisions. By analyzing MNE Network configurations, we capture the end result of a series of location arbitrage decisions over time. This 97 allowed us to identify the dominant logics of those decisions and contextualize when one dominates the other. This paper has typical limitations that can be addressed in future research. For instance, we used a cross-sectional dataset to test our hypotheses while controlling for potential endogeneity issues. Consistent with prior empirical studies, we assumed that an MNE Network configuration in a particular moment of time is a reflection of a series of decisions heralding the time of observation. While our approach is valid, a longitudinal dataset would provide further insight into the phenomenon by allowing for a fine-grained analysis of how such configurations evolve and crystallize over time. However, conducting such a study will require the collection of primary data on the evolution of network configurations over time. Another limitation of the study consists in using average economic distance as a proxy for economizing logic and average institutional distance as a proxy for legitimizing logic at the MNE Network level. While these choices are methodologically reliable and empirically consistent with extant literature, we suggest that a more sophisticated measurement of economizing and legitimizing logics can be achieved by constructing factors with multiple indicators. In addition, while the dataset we used is particularly suitable for the research question we asked, it implies that our findings and their implications may be specific to EM-MNEs. Therefore, caution should be taken when generalizing our conclusions to other MNEs, especially those coming from more advanced economies. In the same vein, recent studies highlighted the difficulty of finding secondary data on EM-MNEs that can be used in studies like ours (e.g., Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008). While our 98 sample of 203 firms has been sufficiently large to test our hypotheses, a larger sample might reveal a stronger effect of the degree of experience on the relationship between IDI and geographic prevalence in host regions, for instance. Similarly, our statistic assessments showed no particular conceptual interest in using HLM to test our model, but adopting a nested analytical approach may prove stronger statistical results for the same interaction. Finally, the predictive power associated with the dominant logic concept may be altered by other factors such as the characteristics of decision makers or occasional shifts in strategy as a result of change in firm leadership or context. One of the strengths of the dominant logic approach is to correct for these factors by focusing on general trends rather than on individual decisions, but an empirical exploration of various moderating factors, such as the decision maker’s bias towards emerging markets, would be of particular interest. The above theoretical implications and design limitations suggest that future research may extend this study in several ways. For instance, we would welcome additional indicators to measure legitimizing logic and economizing logic constructs. International Business and Organization Management scholars should find more inclusive constructs helpful in conducting future research. Another interesting extension of this work would consist in conducting a comparative study that contrasts location choices by EM-MNEs with those made by DM-MNEs. This would contribute to a broader debate on whether EM-MNEs behave differently from DM-MNEs. 99 Finally, given the growing interest in the regional dimension of international phenomena, we suggest that additional studies using the dominant logic approach would help explain why MNEs tend to concentrate their activities in their home regions. This holistic approach is particularly useful in studying the phenomenon because it helps bridge multiple levels of analysis, especially between individual and organizational factors and between economic rationality and cognitive bias. Likewise, the concept of "regional bias" is worth exploring further. Extant literature identified national bias (McCallum, 1995) and intra-national bias (Wolf, 2000) as key factors to market expansion strategies. Regional bias would provide a supra-national dimension of the same phenomenon. 100 References Arregle, J.-l., Beamish, P. W., & Hébert, L. 2009. The regional dimension of MNEs' foreign subsidiary localization. Journal of International Business Studies, 40(1): 86. Arregle, J.-L., Hébert, L., & Beamish, P. W. 2006. Mode of International Entry: The Advantages of Multilevel Methods. Management International Review, 46(5): 597. Asmussen, C. G. 2009. Local, regional, or global? Quantifying MNE geographic scope. Journal of International Business Studies, 40(7): 40. Banalieva, E. R., & Eddleston, K. A. 2011. Home-region focus and performance of family firms: The role of family vs non-family leaders. Journal of International Business Studies, 42(8): 1060-1072. Belderbos, R., Van Olffen, W., & Zou, J. 2011. Generic and specific social learning mechanisms in foreign entry location choice. Strategic Management Journal, 32(12): 1309. Beretvas, S. N. 2007. An Introduction to Hierarchical Linear Modeling. In J. P. Stevens (Ed.), Applied Multivariate Statistics for the Social Sciences: 321-359. Mahwah, NJ.: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Berry, H., Guillen, M. F., & Zhou, N. 2010. An institutional approach to cross-national distance. Journal of International Business Studies, 41(9): 1460-1480. Bettis, R. A., & Prahalad, C. K. 1995. The Dominant Logic: Retrospective and extension. Strategic Management Journal, 16(1): 5-14. Bliese, P. D. 2000. Within-group agreement, non-independence, and reliability: Implications for data aggregation and analysis. In K. J. Klein, & S. W. J. Kozlowski (Eds.), Multilevel Theory, Research, and Methods in Organizations: 349-381. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass, Inc. Bouquet, C., & Birkinshaw, J. 2008. Weight versus voice: How foreign subsidiaries gain attention from corporate headquarters. Academy of Management Journal, 51(3): 577. Brouthers, L. E., O'Donnell, E., & Hadjimarcou, J. 2005. Generic Product Strategies for Emerging Market Exports into Triad Nation Markets: A Mimetic Isomorphism Approach. Journal of Management Studies, 42(1): 225-245. Buckley, P. J., Devinney, T. M., & Louviere, J. J. 2007. Do managers behave the way theory suggests? A choice-theoretic examination of foreign direct investment location decision-making. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(7): 1069-1069. Chen, H., & Chen, T.-J. 1998. Network Linkages and Location Choice in Foreign Direct Investment. Journal of International Business Studies, 29(3): 445-467. Chu-Chia, S. L., & Ivan, P. 2003. Monitoring costs and the mode of international investment. Journal of Economic Geography, 3(3): 261-274. Cuervo-Cazurra, A., & Genc, M. 2008. Transforming disadvantages into advantages: developing-country MNEs in the least developed countries. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(6): 957. de Soysa, I., & Jütting, J. 2007. Informal institutions and development: How they matter and what makes them change. In J. Jütting, D. Drechsler, S. Bartsch, & I. de-Soysa (Eds.), Informal Institutions: How social norms help or hinder development: OECD Development Centre Studies. Dun & Bradstreet. 2009. "Who owns whom" database: v. London: GAP Books. 101 Dunning, J. H. 1998. Location and the Multinational Enterprise: A neglected factor? Journal of International Business Studies, 29(1): 45-66. Dunning, J. H. 2000. The eclectic paradigm as an envelope for economic and business theories of MNE activity. International Business Review, 9(2): 163. Dunning, J. H. 2001. The Eclectic (OLI) Paradigm of International Production: Past, Present and Future. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 8(2): 173-190. Dunning, J. H., & Lundan, S. M. 2008. Institutions and the OLI paradigm of the multinational enterprise. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 25(4): 573. Evans, J., & Mavondo, F. T. 2002. Psychic distance and organizational performance: An empirical examination of international retailing operations. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(3): 515-532. Fortune. 2009. Fortune Global 500, www.fortune.com. Ghemawat, P. 2001. Distance still matters. Harvard Business Review, 79(8): 137. Ghoshal, S., & Bartlett, C. A. 1990. The multinational corporation as an interorganizational network. Academy of Management Review, 15(4): 626. Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., & Kim, H. 1997. International diversification: Effects on innovation and firm performance in product-diversified firms. Academy of Management Journal, 40(4): 767. Hyman, D. N. 1993. Externalities and Public Goods, Modern microeconomics: analysis and applications, Third Edition ed. Homewood, IL & Boston, MA: Irwin. Hymer, S. 1976. The international operations of national firms: A study of direct foreign investment. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J.-E. 1977. The internationalization process of the firm--A model of knowledge development and increasing foreign market commitments. Journal of International Business Studies (pre-1986), 8(000001): 23. Jütting, J., Drechsler, D., Bartsch, S., & de Soysa, I. 2007. Informal Institutions: How social norms help or hinder development: OECD Development Centre Studies. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. 2009. Governance Matters VIII: Aggregate and Individual Governance Indicators 1996–2008, Vol. 2009: Wold Bank. Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. 1999. Organizational legitimacy under conditions of complexity: The case of the multinational enterprise. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 24(1): 64. Krugman, P. R. 1995. Development, Geography, and Economic Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. LexisNexis Academic. 2009. Company Dossier, academic.lexisnexis.com. Li, Q., & Vashchilko, T. 2010. Dyadic military conflict, security alliances, and bilateral FDI flows. Journal of International Business Studies, 41(5): 765-782. Lu, J. W., & Beamish, P. W. 2001. The internationalization and performance of SMEs. Strategic Management Journal, 22(6/7): 565. Luo, Y., & Tung, R. L. 2007. International expansion of emerging market enterprises: A springboard perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(4): 481. Mayer, T., & Zignago, S. 2011. Notes on CEPII’s distances measures. Paris: CEPII. McCallum, J. 1995. National Borders Matter: Canada-US Regional Trade Patterns. American Economic Review, 85(3): 615-623. Mintzberg, H., & Waters, J. A. 1985. Of Strategies, Deliberate and Emergent. Strategic Management Journal, 6(3): 257. 102 Mudambi, R. 2002. The location decision of the multinational enterprise. In P. McCann (Ed.), Industrial location economics. Cheltenham, UK ; Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Nachum, L., & Song, S. 2011. The MNE as a portfolio: Interdependencies in MNE growth trajectory. Journal of International Business Studies, 42: 24. O’Grady, S., & Lane, H. W. 1996. The psychic distance paradox. Journal of International Business Studies, 27(2): 309-309. ORBIS. 2010. Company Report: Bureau van Dijk Electronic Publishing. Orr, R. J., & Scott, W. R. 2008. Institutional exceptions on global projects: a process model. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(4): 562-588. Pehrsson, A. 2006. Business relatedness and performance: a study of managerial perceptions. Strategic Management Journal, 27(3): 265. Peng, M., & Pleggenkuhle-Miles, E. 2009. Current debates in global strategy. International Journal of Management Reviews, 11(1): 51. Peng, M. W. 2002. Towards an Institution-Based View of Business Strategy. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 19(2/3): 251. Peng, M. W., Lee, S.-H., & Wang, D. Y. L. 2005. What determines the scope of the firm over time? A focus on institutional relatedness. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 30(3): 622. Prahalad, C. K., & Bettis, R. A. 1986. The Dominant Logic: A new linkage between diversity and performance. Strategic Management Journal, 7(6): 485-501. Rugman, A., & Sukpanich, N. 2006. Firm-Specific Advantages Intra-Regional Sales and Performance of Multinational Enterprises. International Trade Journal, 20(3): 355-382. Rugman, A. M. 2003. The regional solution: Triad strategies for multinationals. Business Horizons, 46(6): 3. Rugman, A. M. 2005. The regional multinationals: MNEs and "global" strategic management. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Rugman, A. M., & Oh, C. H. 2009. Does the regional nature of multinationals affect the multinationality and performance relationship? International Business Review. Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2004a. A perspective on regional and global strategies of multinational enterprises. Journal of International Business Studies, 35(1): 3-18. Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2004b. Regional transnationals and Triad strategy. Transnational Corporations, 13(3): 1. Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2005. Towards a Theory of Regional Multinationals: A Transaction Cost Economics Approach. Management International Review, 45(1): 5. Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2007. Liabilities of regional foreignness and the use of firm-level versus country-level data: a response to Dunning et al. (2007). Journal of International Business Studies, 38(1): 200. Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2008a. A New Perspective on the Regional and Global Strategies of Multinational Services Firms. Management International Review, 48(4): 397. Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2008b. A regional solution to the strategy and structure of multinationals. European Management Journal, 26(5): 305. Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2008c. The theory and practice of regional strategy: a response to Osegowitsch and Sammartino. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(2): 326. 103 Stimpert, J. L., & Duhaime, I. M. 1997. In the eyes of the beholder: Conceptualizations of relatedness held by the managers of large diversified firms. Strategic Management Journal, 18(2): 111. Taleb, A. 2010. Emerging multinationals from developing countries: Would exposure to eclectic institutional conditions confer unique comparative advantages? In R. Molz, C. Ratiu, & A. Taleb (Eds.), The Multinational Enterprise and Developing Countries: Local versus Global Logic, First ed.: 194-207. London & New York: Routledge. Tallman, S., & Li, J. 1996. Effects of International Diversity and Product Diversity on the Performance of Multinational Firms. The Academy of Management Journal, 39(1): 179-196. Thomas, D. E., Eden, L., Hitt, M. A., & Miller, S. R. 2007. Experience of Emerging Market Firms: The Role of Cognitive Bias in Developed Market Entry and Survival. Management International Review, 47(6): 845-867. UNCTAD. 2008. Top 100 non-financial multinationals, Vol. World investment report 2008: xxxii, 340 p. New York: United Nations. Wolf, H. C. 2000. Intranational Home Bias in Trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(4): 555-563. World Bank. 2007. Annual World Bank Conference on Development EconomicsRegional: v. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. World Bank. 2010. Catalog Sources World Development Indicators: World DataBank. Xu, D., & Shenkar, O. 2002. Institutional distance and the multinational enterprise. The Academy of Management Review, 27(4): 608. Yiu, D. W., ChungMing, L., & Bruton, G. D. 2007. International venturing by emerging economy firms: the effects of firm capabilities, home country networks, and corporate entrepreneurship. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(4): 519-540. Zaheer, S. 1995. Overcoming the liability of foreignness. Academy of Management Journal, 38(2): 341. 104 Appendices Table IV – Home-countries of the 203 EM-MNEs in the Sample Home-country Taiwan South Korea South Africa China India Mexico Brazil Singapore Malaysia Thailand Saudi Arabia Kuwait # MNE 45 39 23 21 20 7 6 5 5 4 4 4 105 Home-country Cayman Islands Hong Kong Chile Venezuela Turkey Nigeria United Arab Emirate Panama Egypt Zimbabwe Netherlands Antilles Colombia # MNE 4 3 3 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Table V - Variables, Measures and Data Sources Type Variable Measure Source Dependent Variable Geographic prevalence indicates whether the EM-MNE prevails in developed markets (positive sign) or in emerging markets (negative sign) Legitimizing logic reflects the tendency of a multinational to enter countries with relatively similar institutional conditions to their home-countries Computed by subtracting the number of subsidiaries located in developing markets from the number of subsidiaries located in developed markets, and the difference is divided by the total number of subsidiaries. It ranges from -100 (all locations in developed markets) to +100 (all locations in emerging markets). Legitimizing logic is assessed by averaging institutional distances in the form of differences between the governance indictors of an MNE’s home-country minus those of the host countries of its subsidiaries. Institutional Distance Index (IDI) is the arithmetic mean of the five indicators at the MNE Network level. Its value ranges from -5 to +5. Computed using network structure and ownership data from ORBIS (2010), Who Owns Whom (2009) and LexisNexis (2009) databases. Economizing logic reflects the general tendency of a multinational to pursue economic opportunities in countries with relatively higher economic growth than in their home-countries Size Economizing logic is measured by averaging economic distances in the form of differences between the GDP growth rates of an MNE’s homecountry minus the GDP growth rates of the host country of each location in their network. The growth rates being used are the average of 10 years (1999-2008) prior to the date of network configuration. A one-year lag was also added to count for time effects. Same as above for location network configuration. Computed using GDP growth ratios from the World Bank’s database (2010). Natural log of total sales in million $US at the end of 2009. ORBIS database (2010). Natural log of the number of years between 2009 and the incorporation date. Dummy variables based on US SIC code. Natural log of the averaged gravity model results at the network level. For each host foreign location, GDP per capita of home-country is multiplied by GDP per capita of host country, and the product is divided by the geographic distance between the two countries using the Great Circle method. Dummy variable indicating whether a subsidiary is located in the homeregion of its parent (1) or in another region (0). Number of foreign subsidiaries divided by the total number of subsidiaries of a given MNE. ORBIS database (2010). Independent Variables Control Variables Age Industry FDI Potential Home Region Moderating Variable Degree of Internationalization Same as above for location network configuration. Computed using the UNCTAD’s six governance indicators (Kaufmann et al., 2009). ORBIS database (2010). Computed using GDP per Capita data from the World Bank’s database (2010) and geographic distance from CEPII database (www.cepii.fr). Same as above for location network configuration. Table VI - Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix Variable Mean 1. Size (sales in billion US$) 13.0 Std. Dev. 21.8 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1.00 2. Age (years) 40.4 30.7 0.04 1.00 3. FDI Potential (billion US$/km) 485.2 2296.8 -0.04 0.01 4. Geographic Prevalence (%) -31.8 49.9 -0.003 0.10 -0.02 1.00 5. Economic Distance Index 2.17 2.1 -0.06 -0.28 -0.06 0.18 1.00 1.00 6. Institutional Distance Index -0.3 0.5 -0.06 0.02 0.06 -0.10 -0.14 1.00 7. Degree of Internationalization (%) 56.5 27.7 0.06 0.03 0.13 0.63 0.14 0.10 1.00 Table VII Statistics on Geographic Prevalence # (%) of subsidiaries in... Home Region Host Regions Total Emerging Markets 5,647 (56%) Developed Markets 299 (3%) Transitional Markets 0 (0%) 5,946 (59%) 625 (6%) 3,478 (34%) 74 (1%) 4,177 (41%) 6,272 (62%) 3,777 (37%) 74 (1%) 10,123 (100%) 107 Total Table VIII - Results of Regression Analyses Variables Worldwide 110.332 Intercept Model 1 (Baseline) Home Region Host Regions -94.949 -46.158 Model 2 (H2) Worldwide -67.047 -35.699 -77.855 Model 3 (H3) Home Region -117.152 -104.949 Model 4 (H4a/b) Host Regions -167.907 -212.278 Model 5 (H5a/b) DOI in Host Regions -166.847 -206.432 Control Variables (a) Industry Size (Ln) Age (Ln) FDI Potential (Ln) DOI Region (inHmR) N/R 1.454 2.890 -7.976* -1.225* N/R 1.782 -3.574 1.440 -0.136 N/R -1.304 1.717 12.461* -0.017 Main Effects IDI EDI IDI^2 EDI^2 N/R -2.297 12.239* 2.445 -0.638* N/R -0.610 4.559* 6.073* 0.046 -136.344* N/R -1.730 12.975* 2.675** -0.621* N/R 0.588 -0.201 2.888* -0.121 N/R -0.354 -0.759 2.473* -0.084 N/R -2.873 7.858* 19.126* 0.142 N/R -1.112 8.699* 21.945* 0.119 N/R -2.822 7.898* 19.118* 0.079 N/R -1.546 8.113* 21.579* 0.169 -52.492* 12.127* -31.021* 3.409* -51.828* 8.675* -0.272 0.712* -6.232 7.793* -7.930* 0.760 -5.842 2.366* -34.558* 6.043* -41.337* 1.388 -5.394 0.901* -37.218* 4.638* -41.895* 4.916 -3.009 0.085 0.085 0.042 0.050 -0.109 -0.055 0.024* 203 203 Interactions inHmR x IDI inHmR x EDI 23.079* 6.109* DOI x IDI DOI x EDI DOI x IDI^2 DOI x EDI^2 # Observations ~ 406 203 203 406 406 406 203 203 203 203 p< 0.1 * p < 0.05 ** p < 0.01 *** p < 0.001 N/R: The beta coefficients of the dummy variables for industry were non-significant and are not reported here for sake of brevity (a) Figure 4 - Moderating Effects of the Degree of Internationalization on the Relationships between Economizing Logic and Geographic Prevalence in Host Regions EDI-DOI Interaction in Host Regions -10 -5 0 5 10 Geographic Prevalence -15 Economic Distance Index High DOI (m+1sd) Medium DOI (mean) 109 Low DOI (m-1sd) 15 Conclusion générale Chacun des trois articles dans cette thèse a sa propre conclusion. Par conséquent, cette conclusion générale a pour objectif de prendre du recul et d’essayer de répondre à la question suivante : qu'avons-nous appris de ces trois articles en tant qu’ensemble intégré ? En répondant à cette question, nous focalisons notre attention sur les logiques de stratégisation et synthétisons nos principaux apprentissages en quatre grands thèmes. Intégration des logiques : Les logiques d’efficacité économique, de légitimité institutionnelle et de pouvoir politique doivent être vues comme un ensemble intégré de lentilles analytiques. Chacune des rationalités sous-jacentes apporte une perspective unique à la compréhension des phénomènes organisationnels. Les deux articles empiriques illustrent clairement comment le pouvoir explicatif d’une logique peut se renforcer quand elle est combinée avec les autres logiques complémentaires. Arbitrage des logiques : Les trois logiques ne sont pas seulement complémentaires, elles interagissent également et s’influencent mutuellement. Les décideurs utilisent leur jugement pour privilégier l’utilisation d'une logique plutôt qu’une autre. Ils peuvent aussi mobiliser plusieurs logiques en même temps. Faire appel au jugement personnel implique la présence éventuelle de subjectivité et de partialité au moment des choix. Le paradigme de distance psychique, par exemple, suggère que les décideurs ont tendance à préjuger des similitudes entre pays alors qu’il n’y en a pas en réalité. Dans le troisième article, nous avons souligné, par exemple, le rôle du biais cognitif dans les décisions d'entrée des firmes des pays émergents dans les marchés xv des pays avancés. Ce biais cognitif pourrait favoriser la persistance et la dominance d’une logique sur les autres même si le contexte varie à travers le temps et l’espace. Contextualisation des logiques : Le contexte de la firme multinationale est à la fois distribué et pluraliste. Comme discuté dans le troisième article, les logiques de stratégisation sont foncièrement ancrées dans le psychisme des décideurs. Ces derniers, à leur tour, sont encastrés dans des environnements multiples et souvent différents. De plus, les parties prenantes impliquées dans les processus organisationnels peuvent avoir des intérêts divergents – et néanmoins légitimes – en fonction du rôle qu’elles jouent dans ces derniers. Le deuxième article a notamment illustré l’importance de contextualiser la prédominance des logiques selon la partie prenante concernée. Dans le transfert d’une même pratique, une petite filiale destinatrice peut rechercher de l'efficacité économique alors que d’une grande filiale originaire de cette même pratique peut rechercher du pouvoir politique et de la légitimité organisationnelle. Le contexte joue donc un rôle essentiel dans l'arbitrage des logiques. Ceci est également apparent dans le troisième article vu que nous focalisons notre attention sur le comportement des firmes multinationales qui sont fortement influencées par le contexte socio-économique des pays émergents. Dimension régionale des logiques : Les deux articles empiriques de cette thèse confirment la pertinence d’étudier la dimension régionale des phénomènes organisationnels dans un contexte international. Ensemble, ils suggèrent que les effets régionaux ne concernent pas seulement les choix de locations (praxis) mais aussi les processus de stratégisation (pratiques). Le troisième article montre que les logiques de stratégisation sont de nature régionale dans la mesure où les décideurs mobilisent xvi des logiques distinctes quand ils font des choix de locations selon la région cible. On y fait notamment la différence entre la région mère de la multinationale et le reste du monde. Quant au deuxième article, il apporte une contribution substantielle à la littérature en explorant la dimension régionale d'un phénomène intra- organisationnel. On y suggère notamment que la logique régionale peut s’appliquer aux phénomènes aussi bien internes qu’externes à l’organisation. En contrastant la vision interne des régions (structure organisationnelle) avec les regroupements des pays en régions géographiques qui sont généralement utilisés dans la littérature (banque mondiale), cet article soulève la question du fit entre les structures formelles et les structures informelles, et de comment la présence ou l’absence de ce dernier influence les processus et les actions des organisations. La question est d’une importance capitale dans la mesure où les structures formelles représentent des mécanismes de contrôle organisationnel alors que les structures informelles nourrissent les représentations collectives et les biais cognitifs des décideurs. Ces quatre thèmes couvrent d’une manière schématique nos apprentissages sur les logiques de stratégisation au sein de la firme multinationale. De futures études permettant de mieux comprendre les dynamiques de ces logiques seront d’une grande utilité aussi bien scientifique que pratique. En particulier, il serait intéressant de comprendre comment ces logiques interagissent ? Comment elles sont arbitrées par les décideurs ? Comment le contexte peut expliquer la mobilisation d’une logique plutôt qu’une autre ? Pourquoi les décideurs changent de logique quand ils choisissent des locations en dehors de la région mère de la firme ? Les réponses à ces questions seront autant plus intéressantes si elles sont explorées dans les contextes distincts des marchés développés et des marchés émergents.