normas para la redacción del proyecto fin de carrera

Transcription

normas para la redacción del proyecto fin de carrera
MASTER THESIS
DISRUPTIVE FACTORS IN THE ELECTRIC
SECTOR: CHALLENGES AND OPPORTUNITIES
Author:
Ander Uterga del Orden
Supervisor:
Jorge Solaun Bustillo
Joaquín de Nó
San Sebastián, February 27th 2015
Executive summary
European countries, and Spain in particular, have historically had a great degree of dependency
on fossil fuels. In 2013, 72% of the Spanish energy consumption was covered by fossil fuels.
In order to reduce this dependence of foreign energy and decrease the impact of energy
consumption on the environment, European countries focused on the environmental
sustainability target of the energy policy trilemma. Green energy policies gave place to the first
disruption of the electric system. In Spain, renewable generation (excluding hydro) grew from
less than 3% of the electricity mix in 2000 to over 26% in 2014. Accordingly, power prices for
domestic consumers increased form below 11 ct€/kWh in 2003 to almost 23ct€/kWh in 2013.
As a consequence, affordability of renewable support was increasingly called into question
which marked the beginning of the end of this first disruption, as European countries started to
reduce renewable subsidies.
Currently, the second disruption is about to come. This time, it will not only be driven by green
energy policies but also by several technological and social drivers:

Green energy policies: they have been traditionally the main driver for renewable energy
expansion, but affordability is increasingly questioned and they are being reduced.
Nevertheless, they are still in place to meet with the 20-20-20 European targets

Competitiveness of renewable technologies: solar PV´s LCOE is already in the range of
0.08-0.14 €/kWh and grid parity is already being reached in the south of Spain. Onshore
wind is already competitive with conventional generation in locations with good wind
characteristics, with LCOE is in the range of 0.05-0.11 €/kWh. There are other less
mature technologies that are gradually reducing their LCOE, such as offshore wind, CSP
and ocean energy

Competitiveness of storage technologies: there is abundant innovation in this field and
some promising technologies are appearing which could solve the main inconvenient of
renewable technologies: intermittency. For instance, EOS energy storage has developed
a zinc hybrid cathode battery with a LCOE of $0.12/kWh and Isentropic offers a PHES
solution with a LCOE of $0.05/kWh
Executive summary | 1

Other technology development: smart grids, HVDC grids and more efficient technology,
combined
with
increasing
environmental
consciousness,
are
giving
place
to
electrification of the energy consumption and the adoption of additional energy
efficiency measures
This disruption will affect the business model and revenues of electric utilities. For instance,
renewable generation expansion could reduce the utilization factors of CCGT power plants
below 7.7% by 2030; distributed generation could decrease system electricity demand in
1,900 million €; energy efficiency measures could reduce energy generation in 2,350 million
€; and electrification has the potential to increase consumed electricity in 1,630 million € if
leveraged correctly. As a consequence, utilities will need to adapt to change, in order to reduce
its impact on their P&L.
Finally, two cases have been analyzed. First, the increasing dilemma of renewable affordability
and technology progress has been studied, based on UK´s offshore wind recent bids. The UK
has moved to a competitive allocation process which is forcing to deploy best practices and
techniques in the renewable industry. This way, they have managed to reduce the economic
impact of renewable support and it is a good reference for other countries of how renewables
should be subsidized. Second, the impact of distributed generation deployment on Spanish
utilities has been modelled. Grid parity will be gradually reached in increasingly more Spanish
regions, but there are some barriers that will slow down a rapid expansion. It has the potential to
cover up to a 6% of total electricity consumption by 2020.
Executive summary | 2
Acknowledgements
The concern to forget any name drives me to express collectively my gratitude to all the people
that have made this project possible.
First of all, I would like to thank Jorge Solaun. He deserves my especial gratitude and
admiration. His continual passion for renewable energy and his large expertise in the electric
sector have made him a fantastic supervisor and a good wisdom source during the elaboration
of this project. I want to extend these acknowledgements to A.T. Kearney and the great people
working here for the opportunity of doing this project and the pleasant treatment received during
these months. I also want to thank the Scottish project team for their advices and support during
these months in A.T. Kearney.
I would also like to express my gratitude to Joaquín de Nó for supervising my work from my
home university, Tecnun.
Finally, I would like to express my gratitude to my family and friends for their continuous support
during my university career. This work would not have been possible without them.
Acknowledgements | 3
Contents
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ........................................................................................................................................... 1
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS .......................................................................................................................................... 3
CHAPTER 1
INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................................................... 11
1.1
MOTIVATION .................................................................................................................................................. 11
1.2
OBJECTIVES .................................................................................................................................................... 12
CHAPTER 2
OVERALL ENERGY LANDSCAPE .................................................................................................... 13
CHAPTER 3
OVERVIEW OF THE SPANISH ELECTRIC SECTOR ........................................................................... 19
3.1
SYSTEM STRUCTURE ......................................................................................................................................... 19
3.1.1
Generation.............................................................................................................................................. 21
3.1.2
Transmission and distribution ................................................................................................................ 26
3.1.3
Commercialization .................................................................................................................................. 28
3.2
KEY MILESTONES AND CURRENT MARKET TRENDS ................................................................................................... 29
3.2.1
Energy Policy .......................................................................................................................................... 31
3.2.2
Technology enablers ............................................................................................................................... 36
3.2.3
Effect of economic cycles ........................................................................................................................ 36
3.3
KEY STRENGTHS AND WEAKNESSES ...................................................................................................................... 37
CHAPTER 4
ENERGY INNOVATION ................................................................................................................. 39
4.1
MOTIVATION FOR INNOVATING .......................................................................................................................... 39
4.2
INNOVATION ORIGIN ........................................................................................................................................ 41
4.3
INNOVATIVE TECHNOLOGIES............................................................................................................................... 46
4.3.1
Generation.............................................................................................................................................. 47
4.3.2
Storage ................................................................................................................................................... 65
4.3.3
Efficiency ................................................................................................................................................ 74
4.3.4
Infrastructure ......................................................................................................................................... 76
CHAPTER 5
CHANGING ELECTRIC SECTOR ...................................................................................................... 78
5.1
DISRUPTIVE FACTORS........................................................................................................................................ 78
5.2
BARRIERS TO THE CHANGE ................................................................................................................................. 86
5.3
2020 AND 2030 SCENARIOS OF THE ELECTRIC SECTOR ............................................................................................ 88
Contents | 4
5.3.1
Scenario 1: base case ............................................................................................................................. 90
5.3.2
Scenario 2: economic affordability policies ............................................................................................ 92
5.3.3
Scenario 3: green policies ....................................................................................................................... 93
CHAPTER 6
POTENTIAL IMPACT ON UTILITY COMPANIES .............................................................................. 95
CHAPTER 7
PRACTICAL CASE 1: CAN WE AFFORD RENEWABLE ENERGY? LEARNINGS FROM UK WIND
OFFSHORE
...................................................................................................................................................108
7.1
UK´S RENEWABLE SITUATION ........................................................................................................................... 108
7.1.1
2020 Objectives .................................................................................................................................... 108
7.1.2
Affordability issue: renewable support called into question ................................................................ 109
7.1.3
Malfunctioning subsidy framework ...................................................................................................... 111
7.1.4
Industry failing to deliver...................................................................................................................... 113
7.2
NEW REGULATORY FRAMEWORK....................................................................................................................... 114
7.2.1
Transition from Renewable Obligation Certificates (ROC) to Contract for Difference (CfD) ................ 114
7.2.2
First CfD allocation round overview ..................................................................................................... 116
7.3
OFFSHORE WIND INDUSTRY EVOLUTION ............................................................................................................. 120
7.4
LEARNINGS ................................................................................................................................................... 133
CHAPTER 8
PRACTICAL CASE 2: CAN DISTRIBUTED GENERATION THREATEN THE STATUS QUO OF UTILITIES IN
SPAIN?
...................................................................................................................................................135
8.1
PROFITABILITY ANALYSIS.................................................................................................................................. 135
8.2
MARKET VOLUME PROJECTION ......................................................................................................................... 137
8.2.1
Methodology ........................................................................................................................................ 137
8.2.2
Detailed projections ............................................................................................................................. 151
CHAPTER 9
CONCLUSIONS ............................................................................................................................157
ANNEX: SHORTLIST OF ENERGY START-UPS AND COMPANIES ............................................................................159
REFERENCES ........................................................................................................................................................163
Contents | 5
Index of figures
FIGURE 2.1: ENERGY CONSUMPTION BY COUNTRIES [BP STATISTICAL REVIEW 2014] ..................................................................... 13
FIGURE 2.2: ENERGY INTENSITY IN THE UNITED STATES (ENERGY USE PER DOLLAR OF GDP, REFERENCE 2005) [“ANNUAL ENERGY
OUTLOOK 2014 WITH PROJECTIONS TO 2040”, EIA - 2014] ........................................................................................... 14
FIGURE 2.3: VEHICLES PER 1,000 HABITANTS [THE WORLD BANK] ............................................................................................ 14
FIGURE 2.4: 2010 WORLD PROVED RESERVES (BILLIONS OF BARRELS) [EIA] ............................................................................... 15
FIGURE 2.5: PRIMARY ENERGY CONSUMPTION BY FUEL (WORLD LEFT, SPAIN RIGHT) [BP STATISTICAL REVIEW 2014].......................... 16
FIGURE 2.6: CO2 EMISSIONS AND ENERGY GENERATION RATIO [BP STATISTICAL REVIEW 2014]....................................................... 16
FIGURE 2.7: WORLD ENERGY GENERATION AND CONSUMPTION BALANCE [IEA] ........................................................................... 18
FIGURE 3.1: SYSTEM STRUCTURE [REE] ................................................................................................................................ 20
FIGURE 3.2: ENERGY GENERATION MIX SPAIN 2013 [REE] ...................................................................................................... 21
FIGURE 3.3: DAILY ELECTRICITY DEMAND PROFILE ................................................................................................................... 22
FIGURE 3.4: EXAMPLE OF ENERGY AUCTION WITH MERIT OF ORDER MECHANISM ......................................................................... 25
FIGURE 3.5: GEOGRAPHICAL FOOTPRINT OF SPANISH DISTRIBUTION UTILITIES............................................................................... 27
FIGURE 3.6: FREE AND REGULATED MARKET COMPARISON [“ANÁLISIS DEL MECANISMO DE FACTURACIÓN DEL PVPC”, CIUDADANÍA Y
VALORES – MAY 2014] ............................................................................................................................................ 28
FIGURE 3.7: SPANISH GENERATION MIX EVOLUTION [BASED ON REE´S ANNUAL PUBLICATIONS] ....................................................... 30
FIGURE 3.8: ELECTRICITY PRICE EVOLUTION (DOMESTIC CONSUMERS, 2,500 KWH < CONSUMPTION < 5,000 KWH) [EUROSTAT] ........ 30
FIGURE 3.9: SYSTEM COST EVOLUTION [SYMPOSIUM BURGOS, CNMC] ...................................................................................... 31
FIGURE 3.10: ENERGY POLICY TRILEMMA [BASED ON “WORLD ENERGY TRILEMMA”, WORLD ENERGY COUNCIL – 2013].................... 32
FIGURE 3.11: THE ENERGY POLICY "SQUARE"......................................................................................................................... 32
FIGURE 3.12: TIMELINE OF RELEVANT EVENTS IN THE SPANISH ELECTRIC SYSTEM........................................................................... 37
FIGURE 4.1: EXAMPLE OF A MOTIVATION MIX ........................................................................................................................ 41
FIGURE 4.2: TECHNOLOGY LIFE-CYCLE CURVE ......................................................................................................................... 43
FIGURE 4.3: PRESENCE OF DEVELOPERS AND FUNDING INSTITUTIONS IN EACH CYCLE ...................................................................... 46
FIGURE 4.4: CLASSIFICATION OF GENERATION TECHNOLOGIES ................................................................................................... 47
FIGURE 4.5: ILLUSTRATION OF THE PARALLEL ARCHITECTURE [TENKSOLAR] .................................................................................. 48
FIGURE 4.6: LEARNING CURVE FOR MODULE PRICE AS FUNCTION OF THE CUMULATIVE PV MODULE SHIPMENTS [BASED ON ITR PV 2013
RESULTS] ................................................................................................................................................................ 49
FIGURE 4.7: THIN-FILM MARKET SHARE BY TYPE [“PHOTOVOLTAICS REPORT”, FRAUNHOFER ISE – OCT. 2014] ................................. 50
FIGURE 4.8: MARKET SHARE BY PV TECHNOLOGY [“PHOTOVOLTAICS REPORT”, FRAUNHOFER ISE – OCT. 2014] ............................... 53
FIGURE 4.9: LCOE EVOLUTION FOR SOLAR TECHNOLOGIES [“LEVELIZED COST OF ELECTRICITY RENEWABLE ENERGY TECHNOLOGIES”,
FRAUNHOFER ISE – NOV. 2013] ................................................................................................................................ 56
Index of figures | 6
FIGURE 4.10: WIND, COAL AND CCGT LCOE COMPARISON [BASED ON “LEVELIZED COST OF ELECTRICITY RENEWABLE ENERGY
TECHNOLOGIES”, FRAUNHOFER ISE – NOV. 2013] ......................................................................................................... 58
FIGURE 4.11: PICTURE OF THE AEROSTAT OF ALTAEROS ENERGY................................................................................................ 59
FIGURE 4.12: ILLUSTRATION OF MAKANI´S PLANE (LEFT) AND PICTURE OF KITEGEN´S KITE (RIGHT) .................................................. 60
FIGURE 4.13: ILLUSTRATION OF THE WORKING PRINCIPLE OF AMPYX POWER´S TECHNOLOGY .......................................................... 60
FIGURE 4.14: ILLUSTRATION OF A WIND FARM WITH SKYSAILS TECHNOLOGY ................................................................................ 60
FIGURE 4.15: ILLUSTRATION OF PELAMIS´ WAVE MOTION GENERATOR ....................................................................................... 62
FIGURE 4.16: STRUCTURE OF WAVE GENERATED AIR COMPRESSION ........................................................................................... 62
FIGURE 4.17: ILLUSTRATION OF A BUOY GENERATOR ............................................................................................................... 63
FIGURE 4.18: REQUIREMENTS OF EACH STORAGE APPLICATION [“ELECTRICITY ENERGY STORAGE TECHNOLOGY OPTIONS”, EPRI – DEC.
2010] ................................................................................................................................................................... 66
FIGURE 4.19: ENERGY DENSITIES FOR DIFFERENT FUELS............................................................................................................ 67
FIGURE 4.20: ENERGY DENSITY OF HYDROGEN IN DIFFERENT STATES [MCPHY ENERGY] .................................................................. 67
FIGURE 4.21: CYCLE OF HYDROGEN STORAGE AS FORMIC ACID [EPFL] ........................................................................................ 68
FIGURE 5.1: ELECTRICITY PRICE AND PV LCOE COMPARISON [EUROSTAT AND LCOE MODEL] ......................................................... 80
FIGURE 5.2: SOLAR IRRADIATION (LEFT) [SOLAR GIS] AND EXAMPLE OF LCOE FOR DIFFERENT REGIONS (RIGHT) ................................. 81
FIGURE 5.3: FOSSIL FUELS PRICE EVOLUTION [EIA AND EUROSTAT] ............................................................................................ 82
FIGURE 5.4: LCOE COMPARISON FOR DIFFERENT GENERATION TECHNOLOGIES [“LEVELIZED COST OF ELECTRICITY RENEWABLE ENERGY
TECHNOLOGIES”, FRAUNHOFER ISE – NOV. 2013] ......................................................................................................... 82
RD
FIGURE 5.5: ADOPTION OF DIFFERENT TECHNOLOGIES [33 SQUARE] ........................................................................................ 87
FIGURE 5.6: ENERGY TRILEMMA BALANCE BY SCENARIO ........................................................................................................... 89
FIGURE 5.7: OVERVIEW OF SCENARIO 1 ................................................................................................................................ 90
FIGURE 5.8: OVERVIEW OF SCENARIO 2 ................................................................................................................................ 92
FIGURE 5.9: OVERVIEW OF SCENARIO 3 ................................................................................................................................ 93
FIGURE 6.1: REVENUES AND EBITDA FOR IBERDROLA SPAIN 2013 (LEFT) AND ENEL GROUP ITALY 2013 (RIGHT) [ANNUAL REPORTS] .. 96
FIGURE 6.2: FREE MARKET WHOLESALE PRICE AND DEMAND EVOLUTION [OMIE] ......................................................................... 97
FIGURE 6.3: STRUCTURE OF SYSTEM COSTS AND GRID ACCESS TARIFF [“ANÁLISIS DEL AUTOCONSUMO EN EL MERCADO DEL SECTOR
ELÉCTRICO ESPAÑOL”, IBERDROLA – MAY 2012] .......................................................................................................... 102
FIGURE 6.4: ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND GRID ACCESS INCOMES BY TARIFFS FOR DISTRIBUTION COMPANIES WITH > 100,000 CONSUMERS
[“INFORME SOBRE LA LIQUIDACIÓN PROVISIONAL 7/2014 DEL SECTOR ELÉCTRICO”, CNMC] ................................................ 103
FIGURE 6.5: POTENTIAL REDUCTION OF DUAL TARIFFS (LEFT) [COMPARADOR DE OFERTAS DE ENERGÍA CNMC] AND SATISFACTION INDEXES
(RIGHT) [EUROPEAN COMMISSION] ........................................................................................................................... 105
FIGURE 6.6: COMMERCIALIZATION MARGINS FOR DIFFERENT COUNTRIES [CNMC, OFGEM, OBSERVATOIRE DE L´INDUSTRIE ELECTRIQUE]
........................................................................................................................................................................... 105
FIGURE 7.1: HISTORIC EVOLUTION OF DOMESTIC GAS AND ELECTRICITY PRICE [“ENERGY AFFORDABILITY: THE RISING TIDE ON UK SHORES”,
A.T. KEARNEY - 2014] ........................................................................................................................................... 109
Index of figures | 7
FIGURE 7.2: DOMESTIC GAS AND ELECTRICITY PRICE PROJECTIONS [“ENERGY AFFORDABILITY: THE RISING TIDE ON UK SHORES”,
A.T. KEARNEY - 2014] ........................................................................................................................................... 110
FIGURE 7.3: AVERAGE CONSUMER DUAL FUEL BILL PROJECTIONS PRICE [“ENERGY AFFORDABILITY: THE RISING TIDE ON UK SHORES”,
A.T. KEARNEY - 2014] ........................................................................................................................................... 110
FIGURE 7.4: PREDICTED AND ACTUAL OFFSHORE WIND LCOE COMPARISON............................................................................... 113
FIGURE 7.5: INITIALLY PROPOSED KEY DATES ON CFD PROCESS [DECC] .................................................................................... 116
FIGURE 7.6: EFFECT OF LARGER TURBINES IN DIFFERENT ASPECTS [“FUTURE RENEWABLE ENERGY COSTS: OFFSHORE WIND”. BVG
ASSOCIATES - 2014] ............................................................................................................................................... 122
FIGURE 7.7: ILLUSTRATIVE OF SUCTION CAISSON WORKING PRINCIPLE ["FOUNDATIONS FOR OFFSHORE WIND TURBINES", UNIVERSITY OF
OXFORD - DEC. 2014] ............................................................................................................................................ 125
FIGURE 7.8: ILLUSTRATIVE OF FLOATING SUBSTRUCTURE ["DEEP WATER. THE NEXT STEP FOR OFFSHORE WIND ENERGY", EWEA - JULY
2013] ................................................................................................................................................................. 126
FIGURE 7.9: HVDC TRANSMISSION STRUCTURE [“OFFSHORE WIND TRANSMISSION STUDY, FINAL REPORT”, ESS GROUP, INC – SEPT.
2014] ................................................................................................................................................................. 129
FIGURE 7.10: INTERFACES BETWEEN TASKS DURING THE CONSTRUCTION OF A WIND FARM [A.T. KEARNEY EXPERIENCE]..................... 131
FIGURE 8.1: STATIC GRID PARITY FOR DIFFERENT SPANISH REGIONS (BILBAO, MADRID AND SEVILLE) .............................................. 136
FIGURE 8.2: INSTALLED CAPACITY AND ENERGY GENERATION 2020 PREDICTIONS OF DISTRIBUTED GENERATION ................................ 137
FIGURE 8.3: ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLE OF METHODOLOGY ......................................................................................................... 138
FIGURE 8.4: ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLE OF THE ESTIMATION PROCESS ........................................................................................... 140
FIGURE 8.5: REGIONS AND GHI BY REGION [NASA SURFACE METEOROLOGY AND SOLAR ENERGY DATABASE] .................................. 140
FIGURE 8.6: PICTURES OF TWO TYPE OF ROOFTOPS. A (LEFT) AND B (RIGHT).............................................................................. 143
FIGURE 8.7: ADOPTION CURVE DEPENDING ON SAVING [BASED ON “CUSTOMER ENGAGEMENT WITH THE ENERGY MARKET – TRACKING
SURVEY 2013”, OFGEM – JUNE 2013]...................................................................................................................... 144
FIGURE 8.8: PROFITABILITY DEPENDENCE CHART ................................................................................................................... 144
FIGURE 8.9: SOLAR PROFILE AND PERIOD DIVISION FOR 3.0A AND 3.1A TARIFFS [BASED ON MINETUR] ........................................ 145
FIGURE 8.10: SOLAR AND CONSUMPTION PROFILE COMPARISON [BASED ON REE AND MINETUR] ............................................... 146
FIGURE 8.11: ADOPTION CURVE FOR THE DIFFERENT MINDSET BARRIER LEVELS ........................................................................... 148
FIGURE 8.12: FLOW DIAGRAM OF METHODOLOGY (1/2). COMMON FOR ALL REGULATORY CASES .................................................. 151
FIGURE 8.13: FLOW DIAGRAM OF METHODOLOGY (2/2). REPEATED FOR EACH REGULATORY CASE ................................................. 151
FIGURE 8.14: SNAPSHOT OF KEY RESULTS FOR CASE 1 ........................................................................................................... 152
FIGURE 8.15: SNAPSHOT OF KEY RESULTS FOR CASE 2 ........................................................................................................... 153
FIGURE 8.16: SNAPSHOT OF KEY RESULTS FOR CASE 3 ........................................................................................................... 154
FIGURE 8.17: STEP-BY-STEP RESULTS OF THE PREDICTION PROCEDURE (1/4) AGRICULTURE SEGMENT ............................................ 154
FIGURE 8.18: STEP-BY-STEP RESULTS OF THE PREDICTION PROCEDURE (2/4) INDUSTRY SEGMENT .................................................. 155
FIGURE 8.19: STEP-BY-STEP RESULTS OF THE PREDICTION PROCEDURE (3/4) COMMERCE SEGMENT ............................................... 155
FIGURE 8.20: STEP-BY-STEP RESULTS OF THE PREDICTION PROCEDURE (4/4) RESIDENTIAL SEGMENT .............................................. 156
Index of figures | 8
Index of tables
TABLE 3.1: OVERVIEW OF GENERATION TECHNOLOGIES [REE AND OWN RESEARCH] ...................................................................... 24
TABLE 3.2: MARKET SHARE OF MAIN UTILITIES IN THEIR TRADITIONAL REGION [“BOLETÍN ESTADÍSTICO SOBRE LA EVOLUCIÓN DEL MERCADO
MINORISTA DE ELECTRICIDAD”, CNMC - FEB. 2104] ...................................................................................................... 29
TABLE 3.3: GERMAN POLITICIAN STATEMENTS ABOUT NUCLEAR ENERGY...................................................................................... 35
TABLE 4.1: CHARACTERISTIC COMPARISON OF MAIN PV TECHNOLOGIES [BASED ON “RENEWABLE ENERGY TECHNOLOGIES: COST ANALYSIS
SERIES, SOLAR PHOTOVOLTAICS”, IRENA – JUNE 2012] ................................................................................................. 52
TABLE 4.2: COMPARISON OF DIFFERENT CSP TECHNOLOGIES [BASED ON “RENEWABLE ENERGY TECHNOLOGIES: COST ANALYSIS SERIES,
CONCENTRATING SOLAR POWER”, IRENA – JUNE 2012]] .............................................................................................. 53
TABLE 4.3: INNOVATION FOCUSES BY TECHNOLOGY AND FIELD [A.T. KEARNEY EXPERIENCE] ........................................................... 54
TABLE 4.4: ESTIMATED LCOE FOR PARABOLIC TROUGH AND SOLAR TOWER TECHNOLOGIES [BASED ON “RENEWABLE ENERGY
TECHNOLOGIES: COST ANALYSIS SERIES, CONCENTRATING SOLAR POWER”, IRENA – JUNE 2012] ........................................... 55
TABLE 4.5 : CHARACTERISTICS OF THE SIX NUCLEAR REACTOR TECHNOLOGIES [GIF] ....................................................................... 64
TABLE 4.6: OVERVIEW OF MAIN CHARACTERISTICS BY STORAGE TECHNOLOGY [BASED ON “THE FUTURE ROLE AND CHALLENGES OF ENERGY
STORAGE “, EUROPEAN COMMISSION] ......................................................................................................................... 73
TABLE 4.7: SAMPLE OF RELEVANT ENERGY EFFICIENCY START-UPS .............................................................................................. 75
TABLE 4.8: SAMPLE OF RELEVANT INFRASTRUCTURE DEVELOPERS ............................................................................................... 76
TABLE 6.1: OVERVIEW OF DISRUPTIVE FACTORS AND CONSEQUENCES ......................................................................................... 95
TABLE 6.2: POTENTIAL IMPACT ON INCUMBENT UTILITY BUSINESS .............................................................................................. 96
TABLE 6.3: WHOLESALE PRICE PREDICTIONS BY SCENARIO ........................................................................................................ 98
TABLE 6.4: ADOPTION AND IMPACT OF ELECTRIC VEHICLES BY SCENARIO.................................................................................... 101
TABLE 6.5: IMPACT CALCULATION OF DG WITH STORAGE ....................................................................................................... 104
TABLE 6.6: SUMMARY OF THE DIFFERENT IMPACTS ON UTILITIES .............................................................................................. 107
TABLE 7.1: EUROPEAN 20/20/20 TARGETS FOR UK [EUROPEAN COMMISSION WEBSITE] ............................................................ 109
TABLE 7.2: RECEIVED RO CERTIFICATES FOR A SAMPLE OF TECHNOLOGIES [DECC] ..................................................................... 112
TABLE 7.3: HISTORIC BUY OUT PRICE FOR RO CERTIFICATES [OFGEM] ....................................................................................... 112
TABLE 7.4: MAIN CHARACTERISTICS OF PROJECTS INITIALLY COMPETING FOR A CFD [4COFFSHORE] ................................................ 117
TABLE 7.5: BUDGET DISTRIBUTION BETWEEN POTS [DECC] .................................................................................................... 118
TABLE 7.6: ADMINISTRATIVE STRIKE PRICE BY COMMISSIONING DATE AND TECHNOLOGY [DECC] .................................................. 118
TABLE 7.7: SAMPLE OF RELEVANT UK OFFSHORE WIND FARMS AND PROJECTS [4COFFSHORE] ....................................................... 120
TABLE 7.8: SAMPLE OF RELEVANT WTG MODELS [4COFFSHORE] ............................................................................................. 121
TABLE 7.9: WIND AND LOCATION CHARACTERISTICS OF A SAMPLE OF WIND FARMS [4COFFSHORE] ................................................. 123
TABLE 7.10: MAIN CHARACTERISTICS FOR THE DIFFERENT FIXED SUBSTRUCTURES [BASED ON “WIND IN OUR SAILS”, EWEA - 2011] ... 124
Index of tables | 9
TABLE 7.11: SAMPLE OF RELEVANT FLOATING PROJECT AND PROTOTYPES ["DEEP WATER. THE NEXT STEP FOR OFFSHORE WIND ENERGY",
EWEA - JULY 2013] .............................................................................................................................................. 126
TABLE 7.12: PICTURES OF PROJECTS IN TABLE 7.11 ["DEEP WATER. THE NEXT STEP FOR OFFSHORE WIND ENERGY", EWEA - JULY 2013]
........................................................................................................................................................................... 127
TABLE 7.13: MAIN ELECTRICAL TRANSMISSION CHARACTERISTICS FOR SAMPLE OF PROJECTS [“OFFSHORE WIND TRANSMISSION STUDY,
FINAL REPORT”, ESS GROUP, INC – SEPTEMBER 2014] ................................................................................................ 128
TABLE 7.14: IMPACT OF SAMPLE OF RELEVANCE RISKS ON PROFITABILITY [A.T. KEARNEY EXPERIENCE] ............................................ 130
TABLE 8.1: DYNAMIC GRID PARITY FOR BILBAO, MADRID AND SEVILLE...................................................................................... 136
TABLE 8.2: SPACE AVAILABILITY BY SEGMENT ....................................................................................................................... 141
TABLE 8.3: SELECTED ACTIVITIES BY SEGMENT ...................................................................................................................... 142
TABLE 8.4: WEIGHTED AVERAGE PRICE CALCULATION FOR 3.0A AND 3.1A TARIFFS..................................................................... 146
TABLE 8.5: SAMPLE OF RELEVANT LCOE MODEL INPUTS ........................................................................................................ 147
TABLE 8.6: CALCULATION OF INVESTMENT PAY-BACK PERIOD IMPACT ....................................................................................... 147
TABLE 8.7: BACK-UP TOLL BY SEGMENT [BASED ON DRAFT RD FOR SELF-CONSUMPTION, JULY 2013] ............................................ 149
TABLE 8.8: CAPACITY PER INSTALLATION BY SEGMENT............................................................................................................ 150
TABLE 8.9: CAPACITY TO ENERGY CONVERSION TABLE............................................................................................................ 150
Index of tables | 10
Chapter 1
Introduction
1.1 Motivation
I have always felt a passion for how technology could transform the world we live in, and this
enthusiasm was the inspiration on my decision to study engineering. Now, five years later, I find
myself at the end of my university formation and keep that passion as fervent as in the beginning
of this journey. Working on this project was very appealing for me, as the energy sector has solid
fundamentals in technology.
As stated by the United Nations in the World Energy Assessment [1], “energy is central to
achieving the interrelated economic, social and environmental aims of sustainable human
development”. It is an essential resource for a developed society as it is required to cover the
basic needs of citizens and to carry out sort of any economic activity.
Traditionally, the electricity activity has been a rigid sector. It was comprehensively regulated
and dominated by a unique (or just a few) player(s). In the last decades however, the energy
landscape has been subjected to several alterations. There is an increasing environmental
consciousness which is leading to “greener” energy policies (e.g. 20-20-20 European targets,
the Kyoto Protocol). Innovation in technology is enabling new business models and new
methods of generating electricity are emerging (e.g. the final consumer generating its energy for
self-consumption). In this context, the energy sector faces an amazing and uncertain future.
A.T. Kearney offered me the possibility to work on this topic, and leverage their industry
expertise to further investigate on the potential innovations that could disrupt the power sector.
To sum up, the motivation for the development of this project is based on my passion for
technology, the possibility to work with an experienced company and the willingness to shed
light to some of the uncertainties that will be faced by the energy sector: which generation
Chapter 1 | Introduction 11
sources will dominate? Will the current system remain sustainable as we know it? Will
consumers like myself generate their own electricity? What will the impact be on electric utilities
P&L?
1.2 Objectives
This project has two main objectives:

Understand the disruptive factors that can drive to a comprehensive transformation of the
system and analyze the potential impact on the electric system and traditional electric
utilities

Apply disruptive factors to real case scenarios
In order to reach those objectives, the following milestones are going to be followed:

Identify promising and innovative technologies on the electric sector

Identify the main drivers for system´s disruption and model their impact on the system,
building on three possible scenarios

Analyze and quantify the impact of each scenario on electric utility companies

Analyze the RES support mechanism transition in the UK and identify shareable
learnings

Identify the main barriers for distributed generation deployment in Spain and quantify its
adoption and impact on electric utility companies
Chapter 1 | Introduction 12
Chapter 2
Overall energy landscape
World´s energy demand is increasing at very fast rates. During the last 50 years, the energy
consumption has more than tripled from 3,765 Mtoe to 12,730 Mtoe (see Figure 2.1). In nonOECD countries the consumption has increased more than six times driven by rapid economic
growth (i.e. from 1,121 Mtoe to 7,197 Mtoe); while in OECD countries it has just doubled (i.e.
from 2,643 Mtoe to 5,533 Mtoe).
Figure 2.1: Energy consumption by countries [BP statistical review 2014]
Predictions are that world´s energy demand will continue growing. IEA predicts that primary
energy consumption would increase over 17,000 Mtoe by 2035 in their New Policies Scenario
[2]. This growth will be led by non-OECD countries, which will increase consumption from the
current 7,197 Mtoe to over 11,000 Mtoe. Energy consumption in OECD countries, on the
contrary, has stabilized around 5,500 Mtoe since 2006 and is predicted to maintain around this
number. This stabilization of OECD countries´ energy consumption may have its origin in two
reasons: energy intensity reduction and moderation of GDP growth. From one side, energy
intensity is a measure of the energy efficiency of a country. It is calculated as units of energy per
unit of GDP. More developed countries usually have lower energy intensities as efficiency
measures have deeper penetration. The trend is that energy intensity will continue decreasing
Chapter 2 | Overall energy landscape 13
(see Figure 2.2). From the other side, the growing rate of OECD countries has slowed down and
figures below 5% of GDP growth are considered good figures (e.g. Spanish economy has grown
below 2% in 2014 and it is considered an excellent growth). Non-OECD countries, on the
contrary, are having faster growing rates (e.g. China has grown over 7% in 2014 and it is
considered a low number). This is reflected in the concept of device saturation. This expression
refers to the fact that the market has reached the maximum density for a certain device. It is
mainly happening in developed countries with different items, e.g. cars per 1,000 habitants, cell
phones per person and number of electro-domestics at houses. Countries in ways of
development, however, are rapidly increasing those ratios nowadays. For example, the case of
vehicles: in Spain there were 433 vehicles per 1,000 habitants in year 2000, increased to 485 in
2007 and has maintain around this number since then. In the case of UK, the situation is similar
to the Spanish one. China, however, has not reached the saturation limit and the number of
vehicles per 1,000 habitants will continue increasing (see Figure 2.3).
Figure 2.2: Energy intensity in the United States (Energy use per dollar of GDP, reference 2005) [“Annual Energy
Outlook 2014 with projections to 2040”, EIA - 2014]
Figure 2.3: vehicles per 1,000 habitants [The World Bank]
Chapter 2 | Overall energy landscape 14
The International Energy Agency (IEA) clssifies the final uses of energy intro four main goups:
industry, transport, others (basically, commerce and residential) and non-energy uses. Coal is
mainly used for power generation (60%), oil in transport (55%) and gas in heating both, industry
and residential (57%). Around half of the power generated is lost and the rest is consumed
mainly by industry (30%) and commerce and residential (40%). There is a small percentage that
is used in transport (~1%), barely insignificant if compared to oil (see Figure 2.7).
The world is highly dependent on fossil fuels, accounting more than 85% of primary energy
consumption. As fossil fuels generate CO2 during their combustion, this dependency is creating
a strong increase of CO2 levels in air (i.e. 398.78 ppm in December 2014 [3]), leading to the
Greenhouse effect. In addition, dependency on fossil fuels gives place to geopolitical issues
between countries. The larger proved reserves lay in Venezuela, Saudi Arabia, Canada, Iraq,
Iran, UAE and Russia (see Figure 2.4). So, other countries (e.g. Europe and China) depend on
them and have to spend large amounts of money annually (e.g. EU´s trade balance deficit in
2011 of 185 billion € [4]).
Figure 2.4: 2010 World Proved Reserves (billions of barrels) [EIA]
As a consequence, world is moving towards a greener way of generating energy, renewable
energy. This trend has special strength in OECD countries. These countries are usually net
importers of fossil fuels and have a greater consciousness of the greenhouse effect. Non-OECD
countries, however, are in a process of fast economic growth, which results in higher energy
needs every short time. The solution to cover these demand increases in a fast and economic
way is fossil fuels. Consequently, the fossil fuel consumption share is larger in non-OECD
Chapter 2 | Overall energy landscape 15
countries and OECD countries are moving quickly towards renewable generation (see Figure
2.5). For instance, in Spain, renewable energy generation, excluding hydroelectric energy, has
increased from 8% of total primary energy consumption to 13% in a three year gap. The result of
this trend is that the ratio between CO2 emissions and energy consumption is being reduced in
OECD countries, while it seems to be stabilized in non-OECD countries (see Figure 2.6).
Figure 2.5: Primary energy consumption by fuel (World left, Spain right) [BP statistical review 2014]
Figure 2.6: CO2 emissions and energy generation ratio [BP statistical review 2014]
Once having seen the energy landscape in the world, the rest of the work is going to be focused
in the electric sector, mainly in Spain, from power generation to its commercialization and
consumption. New technology is appearing and it seems to be able to originate considerable
changes in the way electricity is generated and in the way it is distributed. Moreover, as
explained later in point 3.2, everything tends to go electric: from heating to transport. Overall, the
Chapter 2 | Overall energy landscape 16
electric sector is likely to face several changes in the next years and numerous challenges and
opportunities will appear.
Chapter 2 | Overall energy landscape 17
Figure 2.7: World energy generation and consumption balance [IEA]
Chapter 2 | Overall energy landscape 18
Chapter 3
Overview of the Spanish electric sector
This chapter will focus on the Spanish electric sector. It will first describe how the electric system
works in Spain and assess its current situation. Then, the process and events that have led to
the current situation will be analyzed.
3.1 System structure
The electric system is a complex system where there is a need to generate what is going to be
consumed in each moment, real-time generation. This is done by using a complicated structure
in which the consumers have to be constantly connected to the energy generation sources.
Consumers and producers of electricity are always in contact and every time there is a change
of the demand of a consumer, the supply has to adapt to this change.
In Spain, the involved agents are given by the electric sector law [5] and are the following:

Electric power producers: are those who have the function of generating electric power,
as well as construct, operate and maintain generation facilities

Market operator: assumes the management of the supply and demand offers of electric
energy in the daily market of electric energy

System operator: its main responsibility is to guarantee the continuity and reliability of the
electric supply and the correct coordination between production and transmission
systems. The system operator will be the manager of the transmission grid. The law
assigns this function to Red Eléctrica de España

Transmission grid operator: has the function of transporting electric energy, as well as
constructing, maintaining and operating the transmission facilities. It is responsible for the
development and extension of the transmission grid so that it guarantees the
maintenance and improvement of a grid designed under homogeneous and coherent
criteria. The law assigns this function to Red Eléctrica de España.
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 19

Distribution grid operator: has the function of distributing electric energy, as well as
constructing, maintaining and operating the distribution facilities that are used to bring
electricity to consumption points

Commercializers: are those who, having access to the transmission or distribution grids,
acquire energy for selling it to consumers or other system agents

Consumers: are those who acquire energy for its own consumption. Those consumers
that acquire energy directly from the production market will be denominated Market Direct
Consumers

System load managers: are those that, being consumers, are authorized to resell energy
for energy recharge services
Each of these agents is linked to one of the five activities of the electric sector: generation
(electric power producers), transmission (transmission grid operator), distribution (distribution
grid operator), commercialization (commercializers and consumers) and system management
(market and system operators). Finally, law leaves the door open for a sixth activity with the new
figure of system load managers. Generation and commercialization are liberalized activities
where the first one is responsible for producing electric energy and the last one for selling it to
the final consumer. Transmission and distribution are regulated activities that carry the electricity
from the power plants to the consumers.
Figure 3.1: System structure [REE]
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 20
3.1.1 Generation
The generation activity consists on transforming a primary energy (e.g. nuclear, solar, chemical,
thermal, and wind) into electric energy. Generation technologies can be classified in three main
groups depending on the primary energy used: fossil fuels, nuclear power and renewables. In a
generation mix, all of them need to be present due to the different characteristics that make each
of them necessary in order to have a reliable system with a good quality of service.

Fossil fuels: coal, oil and natural gas (Combined Cycled Gas Turbines). Fuels are burned
to generate heat. Thermal power is then converted into electricity

Nuclear power: fission and fusion. Currently just fission is used, fusion is under
development. Nuclear reaction happens and the heat generated is converted into
electricity

Renewables: wind, solar, geothermal, biomass, hydroelectric and others. Each
technology has its own method of generating electricity depending on the primary energy
Energy demand in Spain1 during 2013 was 246.3 TWh and was covered by the following
technologies [6]:
Figure 3.2: Energy generation mix Spain 2013 [REE]
From the operational point of view of the electric system, the generation sources are classified in
three categories: base load, intermediate and peak units.
1
This and all the following references to Spanish electricity consumption will refer to Spanish peninsula
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 21
Figure 3.3: Daily electricity demand profile
Base load units are used to satisfy the needs of constant or base power. They work constantly
along the year, except when they have to be stopped for maintenance. So, they have to be
reliable and have small operating costs. Usually, nuclear plants or flowing water plants are used
as base generations due to the low cost of fuel. These plants usually have low ramp rates; it
takes long time to change the output power (around hours or days).
Intermediate units, also called cycling units, operate during long periods of time, but unlike base
load units, they do not work always at the same power. They have the capacity to change the
generated power rapidly. Combined cycle gas turbines and coal plants are usually used as
intermediate units.
Peak units only work when the power demand is near to its maximum. They have the ability to
switch on and off quickly and operate just for a few hours each year. Oil plants and pumped
storage hydroelectric plants are the most commonly used.
Each generation technology has its own structure of costs and technical characteristics. The
different power plants are complementary to each other and all of them are necessary in order to
have a good quality of service.

Costs: initial investment and operating costs (fixed and variable operating costs). Usually,
those having low initial investments have high operating costs, and the other way round

Technical characteristics: time to switch on/off or change the amount of power generated;
energy availability
The next table shows a quick insight of the main characteristic of each technology:
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 22
10.9
Mature
0.5
 Not used
any more
Mature
25.3
 Being
displaced
by
renewables
 Emit pollutant
gases
Mature
7
 Radioactive
waste
 Strict security
measures
 Very rigid
Mature
7.9
 Nuclear
moratorium
Mature
19.9
 Maintain
capacity
Mature
22.8
 Increase
capacity
 High levels of
pollutant gases
 CO2 penalties
 Low
efficiencies:
40%-45%
 Peak unit
 Medium capital
investment
 Low fixed costs
 Medium variable
costs
 Very high
opportunity costs
 Supply
reliability
 Flexibility
 High levels of
pollutant gases
 CO2 penalties
 Intermediate unit
 Medium capital
investment
 Low fixed costs
 Medium variable
costs
 High opportunity
costs
 Very high
flexibility
 High
efficiencies: 60%65%
 High reliability
 Low LCOE
 Moderate
levels of
pollutant gases
 CO2 penalties
 Produce
electricity and heat
 Distributed
generation usually
 High
efficiencies: 80%90%
 Supply reliability
 Flexible
 Base load unit
 Very big capital
investment
 High fixed costs
 Small variable
costs
 Low opportunity
costs
 Do not emit
pollutant gases
 High energy
density
 No CO2
penalties
 Supply reliability
 Low LCOE
 Peak unit (except
flowing water, base
load)
 Very big capital
investment
 Medium fixed
costs
 Small variable
costs
 Very high
opportunity costs
(except flowing
water, null
opportunity costs)
 Clean energy
 No CO2
penalties
 Supply reliability
 Flexible (except
flowing water,
rigid)
 Low LCOE
Coal
 Supply
reliability
 Medium
flexibility
 Very low LCOE
Oil
Mature
 Being
displaced
by
renewable
s
 Intermediate unit
 Big capital
investment
 Medium fixed
costs
 Medium variable
costs
 Medium
opportunity costs
Wind
Onshore
Hydroelectric
Nuclear power
(fission)
ration
Cogene-
Fossil fuels
Trends
Disadvantages
Renewables
Features
Installed
power
(GW)
Advantages
CCGT
Technology
 Big capital
investment
 Low fixed costs
 Null variable
costs
 Null opportunity
costs
 Clean energy
 No CO2
penalties
 Scalable
 Low LCOE
 Dependent on
precipitations
 Location
dependent
 Intermittency
 Visual and
acoustic impact
 Location
dependent
Variants
 CCS
 CCS
 Conventio
-nal dams
 Pumped
storage
 Flowing
water
Maturity
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 23
 Clean energy
 No CO2
penalties
 Reduced visual
and acoustic
impact
 Good wind
conditions
 Intermittency
 Location
dependent
 Very high
LCOE
Photovoltaic
 Big capital
investment
 Low fixed costs
 Null variable
costs
 Null opportunity
costs
 Clean energy
 No CO2
penalties
 Cheaper than
solar thermal
 Scalable
 Appropriate for
DG
 Intermittency
 High LCOE
 Location
dependent
 c-Si
 Thin film
 CPV
Solar thermal
 Big capital
investment
 Low fixed costs
 Null variable
costs
 Null opportunity
costs
 Clean energy
 No CO2
penalties
 Molten-salt
storage, reducing
intermittency
 Intermittency
 Needs high
solar irradiation
 Location
dependent
 Very high
LCOE
 Parabolic
trough
 Fresnel
collectors
 Solar
tower
 Dish
stirling
Biomass
 Intermediate unit
 Big capital
investment
 Medium fixed
costs
 Medium variable
costs
 Medium
opportunity costs
 Clean energy
 Supply reliability
 Flexibility
 Location
dependent
 High LCOE
 Clean energy
 Scalable
Ocean
 Very big capital
investment
 Medium fixed
costs
 Null variable costs
 Null opportunity
costs
 Clean energy
Geothermal
 Very big capital
investment
 Medium fixed
costs
 Low variable
costs
 Medium
opportunity costs
Solar
Offshore
 Very big capital
investment
 Medium fixed
costs
 Null variable
costs
 Sea location
 Null opportunity
costs
 Very high
LCOE
 Location
dependent
 Very high
LCOE
Growth
 Tidal
 Marine
currents
 Thermal
 Wave
 Osmotic
0
 Increase
capacity
 Reduce
costs
Growth
4.4
 Increase
capacity
 DG
 Reduce
costs
Growth
2.3
 Increase
capacity
Mature
<1
 Increase
capacity
Emerging
0
 Develoment and
testing
Mature
<1
Table 3.1: Overview of generation technologies [REE and own research]
In Spain, generation is a liberalized activity since 1997. So, there is competence between
electric energy producers, potentially reducing electricity prices. Power prices are usually fixed
by auctions, known as energy markets. These markets follow a Merit of Order mechanism.
Different supply offers are placed from the lowest opportunity cost to the highest opportunity
cost. Opportunity cost is defined as the price in which the used resource could be sold in other
time period. The market mechanism can be graphically seen as in Figure 3.4, where one axis is
the number of MWh offered and the other one the price. Lowest opportunity cost supplies are
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 24
usually renewable technologies (wind, solar, ocean, geothermal and flowing water) that have
almost null opportunity costs because if the resource is not used when it appears, it will be
wasted. Base load units go next, commonly nuclear plants. Intermediate opportunity costs
technologies as coal plants or CCGT come then. Finally, the most expensive supply comes from
gas turbines or hydroelectric plants.
The energy buyers place their demand offers with the price they are willing to pay. All the
demand offers are ordered forming the demand curve. Commercializers usually place offers at
the maximum price to guarantee that they buy the energy needed to supply their customers.
Figure 3.4: Example of energy auction with Merit of Order mechanism
The price is given by the intersection point between the supply and demand curves. All the MWh
sold (those to the left of the intersection point) will have the price fixed by the intersection point.
The Merit of Order mechanism was designed so that base load units had the priority, in order to
ensure reliable and economic energy, followed by intermediate and peak units. Renewable
energy was a minority. In the last years, the exception has become the rule and it has some
effects. First, it has a consequence on the market price. Renewable energy has almost null
opportunity costs, entering the auction at the first positions and moving the supply curve to the
right. So, the intersection between the supply and demand curves is given at lower prices.
Moreover, as the offer curve is moved to the right, technologies with higher opportunity costs, as
coal or CCGT, may not be necessary to fulfill the demand, reducing their annual utilization
factors. These effects will be discussed in greater depth in chapter 6.
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 25
3.1.2 Transmission and distribution
Transmission and distribution grids are the responsible for carrying electric energy from the
generation point to the consumer. They are both regulated activities. Physical grid development
and exploitation is attached to significant scale economies, becoming them a natural monopoly.
So, utilities cannot compete with each other avoiding unnecessary duplications of the grid, which
would mean an unjustified increase of costs.
Transmission
Most transmission lines can be classified into two groups depending on the technology used:
high-voltage three-phase AC and HVDC (High Voltage Direct Current). The first one is the most
commonly used, while HVDC is used for higher efficiencies at very long distances or in
submarine interconnections.
In Spain, the company responsible for transmission is Red Eléctrica de España (REE). The
transmission grid is composed by transmission lines, transformers and others components with
voltages over 220 kV and by the international connections lines. There are more than 41,200 km
of lines, more than 5,000 substations and a transformation capacity higher than 78,000 MVA.
The transmission activity has the following objectives:

Minimize transmission losses

Transfer energy between different substations in the grid

Guarantee the balance and security of the electric system

Maintain basic parameters (frequency and voltage) inside the required levels in every
point of the grid

Adapt the resources used depending on the demand
The retribution to the transmission activity is regulated and calculated as the sum of three terms:

Remuneration linked to the present value of the investment

A term that permits to recover operating and maintaining costs

Incentives to the availability and efficiency of the infrastructure
Distribution
The distribution grid is responsible for carrying electric energy from the end of the transmission
grid to the consumers. There are usually three voltage ranges in the distribution grid, known as
subnets: high voltage, medium voltage and low voltage subnets.
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 26
High voltage subnets are connected to the transmission grid in the substations. These subnets
distribute electricity around big consumption centers forming rings. Voltages from 50 kV to 132
kV are used. These subnets are connected to distribution transformation stations where power is
transformed into medium voltage.
Medium voltage subnets distribute electric energy across consumption centers radially. They
carry the electricity from the distribution transformation stations to the transformation centers.
Medium voltage subnets contain voltages from 5 kV to 24 kV.
Finally, low voltage subnets connect the transformation centers with the end costumers. They
usually use 220/380 V.
Distribution covers a series of obligations:

Measuring the consumption of the end consumer

Operating and maintaining the electrical grid that goes from the transmission grid to the
consumer

Planning and building new installations to meet the new supply demands

Ensuring the required quality and supply guarantee

Applying the consumers the access tariffs

Informing the regulator and other competent authorities
In Spain, there are five big distribution companies that cover almost the 100% of the grid (see
Figure 3.5): Iberdrola, Endesa, Gas Natural Fenosa, EDP and E.ON Spain (Sold to Macquaire in
December 2014).
Figure 3.5: Geographical footprint of Spanish distribution utilities
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 27
3.1.3 Commercialization
Commercialization consists on delivering electric energy to the final consumer, having an
economic compensation for it. Commercializers buy electricity in the energy market and supply it
to consumers. These companies have to make an estimation of which the demand of its clients
is going to be and plan how much to buy. In order to bring electricity to the consumer, they make
use of the transmission and distribution grids, paying a price fixed by the government.
Since 1997, commercialization is a liberalized activity in Spain. However, it is not a completely
free market. In 2009, TUR (Tarifa Último Recurso1) was introduced. It is a regulated tariff with
the purpose of guaranteeing affordable energy for domestic consumers. In the new law of the
electric sector in 2013, it was substituted by the PVPC (Precio Voluntario para el Pequeño
Consumidor2). PVPC is the maximum reference price for costumers of <10 kW contracted
power. It is calculated as the sum of: the hourly price of energy in the daily market, the access
tariff and a fixed margin for the commercializer. In 2013, the 57% of the access points had the
PVPC tariff, while they only accounted for the 17% of the consumed energy.
Figure 3.6: Free and regulated market comparison [“Análisis del mecanismo de facturación del PVPC”, Ciudadanía y
Valores – May 2014]
Companies offering the PVPC are called reference commercializers. There are five of them [7]:
Endesa Energía XXI, Iberdrola Comercialización de Último Recurso, Gas Natural S.U.R., EDP
Comercializadora de Último Recurso and E.ON Comercializadora de Último Recurso. As it can
be seen, reference commercializers and distribution companies belong to same corporates. As a
consequence, they have traditionally dominated the commercialization in the regions they had
the distribution grids. It is a barrier for new entrants or the entrance of other reference
1
Last Resource Tariff
2
Voluntary Price for the Small Consumer
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 28
commercializers in their non-traditional regions. The following table shows the consumer share
of each of the commercializers in their traditional regions. All of them dominate their traditional
regions in the free market and have shares over 90% in the case of the regulated tariff.
Table 3.2: Market share of main utilities in their traditional region [“Boletín estadístico sobre la evolución del mercado
minorista de electricidad”, CNMC - Feb. 2104]
Additionally, there are some new players entering to the commercialization activity. They can be
classified into two groups: low-cost and green players. Aura Energía and Alcanzia are some
examples of low-cost commercializer, while Fenienergía and Zencer are some of the green
commercializers.
An important concept in the commercialization activity is the switching rate. It can be used as the
measure of the existing competence. The Spanish switching rate in 2012 was 11.6%.
3.2 Key milestones and current market trends
Spanish generation mix has had lot of changes from the beginning of the 21st century until now.
First, coal and nuclear energy dominated the mix with more than 73% of the share and
renewable energy was just below 3%. By 2008, combined cycles were the main source of
generation (~32%) and renewables reached the 13%. Coal and nuclear production had
decreased from the 73% to a 37%. In 2013, renewable energy was the main primary energy with
a share of 27% while combined cycles have reduced their production to a 9%.
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 29
Figure 3.7: Spanish generation mix evolution [based on REE´s annual publications]
In the meantime, in 2006, power prices start increasing rapidly with an annual average growth of
10%, from 11.5ct€/kWh in 2006 to 22.7ct€/kWh in 2013 (see Figure 3.8). This increase has
mainly its origin in the access cost increase, happening from 2004 (see Figure 3.9).
Figure 3.8: Electricity price evolution (Domestic consumers, 2,500 kWh < Consumption < 5,000 kWh) [Eurostat]
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 30
Figure 3.9: System cost evolution [Symposium Burgos, CNMC]
Do these two events have relation between them? What has originated such a change in one
decade? There are three types of reasons underlying to these evolutions: energy policy,
technology enablers and effect of economic cycles.
3.2.1 Energy Policy
Before digging deeper on which the policies have been, it is important to explain the paradigm
that rules the energy sector. A country´s energy system is always a trilemma between energy
security, energy equity and environmental sustainability [8]. It is a balance in which if a lot of
weight is given to one of those, the others lose power. For instance, a country that wants to
guarantee supply the 100% of the time whatever the situation is, will have to neglect
competitiveness and have a more expensive energy. Spanish situation in year 2000 was close
to the energy equity. During the last decade it moved towards environmental sustainability,
sacrificing competitiveness as it can be seen on power prices evolution. Finally, it seems that in
the last years it is again moving back to affordability.
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 31
Figure 3.10: Energy Policy trilemma [based on “World Energy Trilemma”, World Energy Council – 2013]
However, in the last years, there is a fourth factor that seems to be trying to enter into this
trilemma, becoming an energy policy square (see Figure 3.11): social acceptance. It is becoming
increasingly important what people think about each generation technology. Nowadays, it is not
enough having a green, economic and reliable source of energy, it has to go through people´s
approval. A good example could be the situation of wind energy. It is a renewable technology
that does not emit greenhouse gases, it is competitive in locations with good wind characteristics
but some people do not like it because their blades kill birds or wildlife in mountains is destroyed
during their construction. More examples of this phenomenon are mentioned in point 5.2 talking
about the barriers that the system has to change.
Figure 3.11: The energy policy "square"
There are two types of policies affecting the Spanish electric sector: international and national
policies.
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 32
International policy:

Kyoto Protocol [9]: it is an international agreement linked to the United Nations
Framework Convention on Climate Change which commits its Parties by setting
internationally bidding emission reduction targets. It was adopted in Kyoto, Japan, on 11
December 1997 and entered into force on 16 February 2005. The first commitment
period started in 2008 and ended in 2012. The protocol places a heavier burden on
developed nations under the principle of “common but differentiated responsibilities”. In
the Spanish case, the commitment was to reduce the emissions to a 92% of the base
year

Doha amendment to the Kyoto Protocol [10]: it took place in Qatar on 8 December 2012.
New commitments were agreed to take in a second commitment period from 1 January
2013 to 31 December 2020. During the first commitment period, 37 industrialized
countries and the European Community committed to reduce GHG emissions to an
average of five percent against 1990 levels. During the second commitment period,
Parties committed to reduce GHG emissions by at least 18 percent below 1990 levels in
the eight-year period from 2013 to 2020

20-20-20 European targets [11]: in 2007 the EU made a unilateral commitment to reduce
its greenhouse gas emissions. This commitment sets three key objectives for 2020:
o
A 20% reduction in EU greenhouse gas emissions from 1990 levels
o
Raising the share of EU energy consumption produced form renewable
resources to 20%
o
A 20% improvement in the EU´s energy efficiency
As these measures show, during the end of the 20th and the 21st century, the international
context was moving towards environmental sustainability. This had an impact on the Spanish
energy system, increasing the power generated by renewables.
These policies set the targets that each country has to fulfill, but each government has the
freedom to use the desired mechanism and policies. In the Spanish case, the followings are the
measures taken to reach international objectives.
National policy:
There have been lots of changes in the law since 1997 and just the most relevant ones are
going to be exposed next:

Ley 54/1997: liberalization of the generation and commercialization activities in Spain
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 33

Ley 34/1998: established the legal framework to the activities of transportation,
distribution, storage, regasification and supply of the agents that take part in the gas
sector

RD 661/2007: subsidies for especial regime are fixed. The support follows a Feed-In
Tariff method, this is, generators are paid an extra amount of money over the market
price for each kWh

RD 1/2012: especial regime subsidies are suspended for already installed and new
power plants

RD 9/2013: especial regime, transmission and distribution retribution is fixed as the
interest of Spanish 10 year’s debt plus an additional interest

Draft RD for self-consumption, July 2013: it fixes a limit of 100 kW and introduces the
back-up toll, which is a tariff that a distributed generator has to pay for each kWh it
generates, not taking into account if it is introduced to the grid or self-consumed

Ley 24/2013: new electric sector law that replaces the 54/1997 law
The law 54/1997 makes a movement towards competitiveness by liberalizing generation and
commercialization activities. The Spanish electric sector was close to the energy equity and had
low power prices.
The law 34/1998 tries to impulse the natural gas consumption for heating purposes in Spain.
Natural gas has some important benefits: it is a green source of energy compared to coal and oil
with low pollutant emissions; it relatively easy to transport and distribute using pipelines; and it is
economic in comparison to other fossil fuels. Combined cycles took advantage of this
regasification process in Spain and expanded rapidly, as Figure 3.7 shows.
An important proportion of the access cost increase comes from the tariff deficit. It has its origin
in year 2000 and it is a debt that the system/consumers owe to electric utilities. It is originated by
the difference between the system costs and incomes and reached an amount of 30 billion € in
2014 [12]. It can have two origins: estimation errors or governments´ political objectives. The last
one seems to be the one that has been actually happening. Governments have constantly
underestimate system costs in order to reduce the effect of the electric bill increase for political
purposes. Nowadays, it has become the third main expense of the access costs (see Figure
3.9).
With the RD in 2007, Spain makes a change towards environmental sustainability by supporting
heavily renewable generation. This increases the adoption of renewable energy (see Figure 3.7).
However, it also raises considerably power prices (see Figure 3.8). Renewable expansion also
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 34
meant that other generation technologies with higher opportunity costs were less used, such as
coal and combined cycles.
At the end of 2011, a new government comes into power and, as a consequence of the deep
economic crisis that Spain was submerged in, it tried to move towards energy equity again by
suspending the especial regime support scheme. In the RD 9/2013, renewable generation and
T&D activities are considered low risks activities and their profitability is linked to country´s 10
year´s interest, which means considerable reductions compared with the RD 661/2007.
Moreover, the draft RD indicates the probable intention of the government to penalize distributed
generation with a tariff for each kWh generated. Although it was just a draft RD and it has not
gone on for the moment, it generated fear and distrust among those aiming to install their selfconsumption plant and obtained the slowing down of distributed generation [13]. As a result of
these last measures, renewable energy production is affected and almost frozen.
Other relevant events
Nuclear catastrophes, like Chernobyl in 1986 or Fukushima in 2011, have impact on the social
acceptance and make people change of opinion about nuclear energy. This effect is clear in
Germany. Statements, before and after Fukushima, of some German politicians are an evidence
of this (see Table 3.3):
Table 3.3: German politician statements about nuclear energy
Although in the Spanish case it is not as clear as in Germany, disasters as those make people
change of opinion and create a movement in the energy policies square towards social
acceptance.
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 35
3.2.2 Technology enablers

Electrification: it means that things start working with electricity instead of other energy
sources. The electric consumption per capita and the grade of electrification are clear
measures of country´s well-being. So, as a country develops and new technologies are
adopted, the electrification levels will grow. As a consequence, the need of electricity has
grown and will grow, while the use of other primary energies will reduce. Heating, cooking
and vehicles are some good examples of electrification

Renewable LCOE reduction: great amounts of money are being invested in R&D and
renewable energy reduces its costs progressively, improving LCOE. It is the key for
renewable energy generation expansion

Capacity to manage more complex grids: the entrance of renewable energy brings with it
the necessity of a more complex grid. This implies the usage of new technology that
permitted to manage grids better (e.g. smart grids, smart meters), translating in higher
power prices, as happened from 2007

Unconventional oil/gas: this is a huge revolution that happened during the end of the last
decade. A new way of extracting oil and gas is discovered, fracking. Suddenly, USA
passes from being an oil and gas importer to be self-sufficient and produce its own
resources. One consequence of this is that they increase their generation of power using
their gas, and the coal consumption decreases. They start exporting coal and its price is
reduced, leading an increase on the coal consumption for power generation in Europe, as
it can be seen in Figure 3.7 that happens from 2010 onwards
3.2.3 Effect of economic cycles
Economic prosperity brings with it more electricity consumption: businesses are created, people
buy houses in different places… which means that the grid has to be scaled to those
necessities. This effect was especially big in Spain, where new urbanizations were built
anywhere. Each new house in each new urbanization needed a new connection to the grid. So,
the distribution grid was made bigger and lots of new connections were installed. The problem
comes when things do not go so good. The economic crisis that Spain has gone through since
2008 brought two imbalances:

Unoccupied houses: plenty of those new houses constructed resulted being unoccupied.
Spain ended having a lot of new unoccupied houses with their own grid connection point.
The new grid section has to be maintained, incurring in costs. However, as houses are
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 36
not occupied, there are not revenues generate by them. So, those costs are distributed
across all the consumer´s bills, leading to power price increases

Demand decrease (i.e. from 265 TWh in 2008 to 246 TWh in 2013): as less energy was
sold, incomes were lower and grid O&M costs remain equal or larger (the grid is the
same or bigger than it was in the previous years). So, the proportion of each kWh price
destined to pay the grids had to increase
Figure 3.12 shows the relevant events that have influenced the Spanish electricity sector
ordered chronologically.
Figure 3.12: Timeline of relevant events in the Spanish electric system
3.3 Key strengths and weaknesses
Before going on with the work, it is important to make especial emphasis on the strengths and
weaknesses of the current electric system. Overall, it is a reliable, high quality and diversified
system. The liberalization of generation and commercialization activities increased competence
and companies of the energy industry with international presence guarantee the latest and most
sophisticated technology in generation and grids.
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 37
There are several weaknesses too. Having a reliable supply and diversified generation mix has
resulted in expensive electricity. Furthermore, planning of new power plants was done with the
belief of low renewable penetration. The actual penetration, however, was considerable and
resulted in overcapacity of generation and problems in the integration of this new renewable
capacity. Finally, regulation has been biased by the political opinions of the different
governments. This has led to several changes in energy policies (see Point 3.2.1) and has
created a large tariff deficit and legal distrust between investors.
Chapter 3 | Overview of the Spanish electric sector 38
Chapter 4
Energy innovation
The results of the great efforts done in energy innovation are the creation of many new
technologies and the development, cost reduction and efficiency improvement of the existing
ones. Overall, the focus goes in greener technologies and there are some that could be
competitive with conventional techniques in the short run. The possible electric system
disruption is going to have innovative technologies as one of the main pillars.
In this chapter, motivation for energy innovation is going to be discussed first: what impulses
companies, governments and people in general to innovate. Then, innovation origin is going to
be explained: how innovation is created and who is doing it. Finally, energy innovation itself:
which technologies are being developed, which companies are developing them and trends for
each technology.
4.1 Motivation for innovating
Innovation has its origin in two bases: social and economic aspects. Each of them gives place to
two purposes; reduce environmental impact of energy consumption and ensure universal access
to energy in the case of the social aspect; direct profit and improve brand & corporate image in
the economic case.

Reduce environmental impact of energy consumption: conventional fuels emit large
quantities of greenhouse and other pollutant gases. Greenhouse gases make the earth´s
surface temperature increase, and pollutant gases, as SOx and NOx, create acid rain.
The atmospheric abundance of CO2 has increased a 40% since 1750, reaching an
amount of 390.5 ppm in 2011. Atmospheric nitrous oxide (N2O) was 324.2 ppb in 2011, a
20% increase since 1750 levels. The greenhouse effect is creating a too fast change in
the temperature (i.e. 0.72ºC increase over 1951-2012 [14]), extinguishing some species
and increasing the sea level due to North and South Pole ice melting. Moreover, fossil
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 39
fuels will run out sooner or later. So, there are people starting to believe that something
has to be done in order to avoid it and who think that the best way is to reduce our
dependency to fossil fuels, generate energy in a more friendly way and reduce human´s
impact on earth

Ensure universal access to energy: there are nearly 1.3 billion people without access to
electricity and 2.7 billion people rely on the traditional use of biomass for cooking [15].
Lack of access to electricity usually happens due to three reasons: 1) energy is too
expensive and people cannot afford it (e.g. 16.6% of Spanish citizen were on risk of
energetic poverty in 2012 [16]), 2) the lack of sufficient infrastructure in non-developed
countries (i.e. 57% of African citizen do not have access to electricity [17]) or 3) the
difficulties (high costs) to transport energy to some places of difficult access (e.g. high
mountains, islands, poles or low density areas). So there are people motivated to develop
energy generation, transmission and distribution techniques to reduce their costs and
make them affordable for everyone; or to discover new cheap ways of distributed
generation for remote places with difficult access to the grid. In conclusion, making
possible that every single human can use energy at an affordable price

Direct profit: world´s biggest 50 utilities have revenues of almost 400 billion$, while this
number is around 4,400 billion$ for the biggest 50 O&G companies [18]. The average net
profit margins are 11.72% and 10.35% respectively. Profits are used to give returns to
shareholders, develop technology or make new investment. These new usages of the
profits will give back new profits, repeating the cycle again. These cycles create wealth
and jobs, helping to the development of the society. So, companies innovate for two
purposes: increase profits (by having bigger margins or increasing activity) and assure
future profits by placing on a strategic position. Strategic position in the future: renewable
energy is predicted to gain share in the energy mix and is likely to become the main
source of energy in the far future. It is a reality that is coming slowly but that will become
true earlier or later. Innovation in new energy production techniques brings the
opportunity to play an important role in the coming energy future. In the meantime, there
are companies developing renewable energy as a defense strategy, in order not to stay
out of market in the case of a sudden change of the energy landscape and lose their
current revenue sources
On the other hand, national governments invest on energy innovation in order to reduce
their country´s dependency to foreign energy. In the case of Europe, big quantities of oil
and gas are imported (i.e. over 3,570 million barrels in 2013 [19]). Reducing the
dependency to this energy would reduce the vulnerability to an increase of price, give
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 40
stability to the economy, create jobs and increase wealth (i.e. 388 billion € spent on crude
oil imports in 2013 in Europe could have been used in other purposes [20])

Improve brand & corporate positioning: in the recent past, as the environmental
consciousness is increasing, it is becoming “cool” to be a green person/company/country.
One example could be the case of P&G. Among other environmental sustainability
measures, the company has the objective of powering its plant by a 30% of renewable
energy by 2020. The use of renewable energy is currently ~7.5% [21]. It gives them the
image of a clean and sustainable company. So, there are some companies doing it in
order to improve their image and to use this as a marketing tool
The motivation of a company or a government for innovating is not unique. It is usually a
combined mix of various reasons. Some reasons have greater relevance than others and have
more influence at the time of taking the decision to innovate; these are going to be called
“primary motivations” and the others, “secondary motivations”. A real example can be seen in
the following table:
Figure 4.1: Example of a motivation mix
4.2 Innovation origin
Innovation has its origin in two bases. Both need of each other in order to innovate. The first one
is people who has the ability, the infrastructure and willingness (due to the previous mentioned
motivation mix) to develop technology and create innovation. These have been called
technology developers. However, innovation requires money to invest in equipment, people and
other kind of resources. Moreover, innovation is an investment that gives its returns in the longterm. So, they have the need of the second base, funding institutions. People that have the
money to invest in something, but do not have the capacity, ability or willingness (because their
business is based in other activities) to develop technology themselves. It may happen that a
technology developer is a funding institution at the same time.
Before going on with the technology developers and funding institution, it is important to explain
the different stages that technologies go through during their lives. These stages are classified
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 41
by the grade of maturity, from newly created technologies to obsolete technologies: emerging,
growth, maturity and decline.

Emerging: these are newly created technologies, or even technologies that are on ways
of being discovered. First, ideas are developed and new technologies, materials… are
discovered. Then, they are developed and tested. And finally, small prototypes are made
to verify that they work as expected. Many ideas or technologies may not be as good as
initially thought and are discarded. Others, even if they work as expected, take a long
time to arrive to the next stage because they are very expensive or are not deployable at
big scales at that moment. As these technologies are in early stages, they cannot be
sold, so there is usually a big need of funding. One example of an emerging technology is
the technology being developed by a scientist group of the École Polytechnique Fédérale
de Lausanne (EPFL) that transform hydrogen into formic acid

Growth: already small-scale proven technologies that are commercialized to obtain
economic revenues. Usually, a real scale prototype is done to show the potential buyers
that this new technology is working as expected and it is deployable. The focus on this
stage is to build a new product that is price and performance competitive in order to start
selling it. There is usually a huge need of funding, especially at the beginning, to build the
first units of the product. Moreover, if the product is successful, it has a fast expansion.
An example of a technology in the growth stage is thin film PV. It is a technology that is
already being commercialized, but it is expected to develop and improve efficiency
considerably

Maturity: highly consolidated technologies. Their cost is not going to have significant
reduction. This is a stage where companies deploy widely the technology and make profit
with it. New technologies start entering into the market and taking their place. Onshore
wind is an example of a mature technology. There are already more than 100 GW
installed in Europe [22] and very small LCOE reductions are expected (see onshore wind
section in point 4.3)

Decline: technologies that start to be obsolete, there are new superior technologies in the
market that are cheaper and more efficient. Sales and installed capacity of these
technologies decrease. Finally, its use is minimum. The clearest example of a mature
technology in the electric sector is oil power plants. In Spain, its use has gone to 0 during
the last years
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 42
Figure 4.2: technology life-cycle curve
Each funding institution or technology developer is present in certain stages. Motivations are
closely related to the stage in which they are present. Emerging technologies are often related to
the social purposes, and growth, maturity and decline to the economic purposes.
Technology developers:
There are five main types of technology developers in the energy sector: universities, research
centers, start-ups, technological companies and utilities.

Universities: they do basic research in early stages of the technology. It is not innovation
itself, it is just the base research from which new technologies, new materials, new
techniques are discovered and is the key to then create innovative technologies. It is
usually done by professors and students. They usually have limited resources from the
university, so have the need of funding. Main institutions for funding are the university
itself, government support and utilities. For example, the Altaeros Energy´s high altitude
aerostat and Ambri´s liquid metal battery have their origin in the MIT University. Primary
motivations: reduce environmental impact and ensure universal access to energy.
Secondary motivations: direct profit and improve brand & corporate positioning

Research centers: from basic to applied research (emerging and early growth) is done,
and the technologies usually take long time before being widely deployed. They are often
associated to a university. There are two kinds of centers depending on the ownership:
public property (e.g. Sandia, NREL, CIEMAT and CSIC) and private property (e.g.
Fraunhofer Institut, CTAER, and CEIT). However, both types of centers have similar
ways of funding: companies and specially, government support. As research centers are
usually non-profit organizations, when a potential successful product is discovered, a
spin-off company is created to commercialize it. As a consequence, many technological
start-ups have their origin as a spin-off of a research center. CPV and organic cells are
some examples of technologies that have been developed in research centers. Primary
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 43
motivations: reduce environmental impact and ensure universal access to energy.
Secondary motivations: direct profit and improve brand & corporate positioning

Start-ups: focused on commercializing already developed technologies that may be
successful. They are present in the growth and maturity stages of a technology. Start-ups
often have similar development processes: build a commercial, real scale prototype and
prove it works; commercialize it; and keep doing research and development in order to
improve the product and make it more competitive (i.e. reduce material costs, improve
efficiency, reduce manufacturing costs). Start-ups are newly stablished companies that
initially do not have enough money, so they have the need of funding until they start
selling the product and have revenues. There are plenty of technologies developed by
strat-ups. For instance, smart home solutions (e.g. Wattio), high altitude wind solutions
(e.g. Makani) or thermal energy storage technologies (e.g. Isentropic). Primary
motivations: direct profit. Secondary motivations: reduce environmental impact and
ensure universal access to energy

Technological companies: they are present in all the stages of a technology, from
emerging (not to stay behind its competitors or to place in a better and more advanced
position than competitors) to maturity (have profits from the developed technologies).
Apart from doing basic R&D themselves, it is common that they have agreements with
universities and research centers, or to have energy venture capitals (this is a good way
to become owners of already successful technologies). Technological companies are big
businesses that have enough money to fund their R&D activities, so there is commonly
no need of external funding. Siemens (HVDC and WTGs1) and Abengoa Solar (CSP and
thermal storage) are some examples of technological companies innovating in the energy
sector. Primary motivations: direct profit. Secondary motivations: improve brand &
corporate positioning, reduce environmental impact and ensure universal access to
energy

Electric utilities: their business is generation, distribution and commercialization of
electricity. They build and operate generation plants and distribution grids. So, their focus
is on acquiring already developed and proven technologies to apply them in their
projects. They are mainly in the maturity and decline stages. However, there are also
some efforts dedicated to do R&D. Most of this R&D is oriented to grids management due
to the fear of a probable change in the generation and distribution system. Utilities usually
1
Wind Turbine Generator
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 44
fund projects of universities or start-ups and own energy venture capitals in order to
always have the latest technology and be able to use it. They usually have subsidiary
companies dedicated to renewable energy. As utilities are commonly big companies, they
have enough money for R&D activities without the need of external funding.
Nevertheless, they may need external funding to finance big projects (e.g. nuclear power
plants construction, offshore wind plant construction). For instance, EDP is developing a
floating offshore wind turbine and SaskPower has built the first coal plant with CCS.
Primary motivations: direct profit. Secondary motivations: improve brand & corporate
positioning, reduce environmental impact and ensure universal access to energy
Funding institutions:

Public sector: supports basic research and start-ups in early phases of development.
Governments often support renewable energy plant construction. Public sector plays an
important role on the establishment of new technologies, which initially are not
competitive against established technologies and need a government subsidy in order to
be economically attractive. As those technologies are deployed (subsidized) the sector is
learning and reducing their costs, making them more competitive. Worldwide,
governments spent 14 billion$ for technology development in 2013 [23]. Primary
motivations: reduce environmental impact and direct profit. Secondary motivations:
ensure universal access to energy

Energy venture capitals/private equities: they look for start-ups in the growth stage with a
very promising and disruptive product. It is a high risk business in which they become
owners of a certain percentage of the company. Venture capitals and private equities
contributed to funding technology development with 4 billion$ in 2013 [24]. Primary
motivations: direct profit. Secondary motivations: reduce environmental impact and
ensure universal access to energy

Utilities/technological companies: as stated before, these companies fund projects from
universities, have their own energy venture capitals and have cooperation agreements
with start-ups. Worldwide, corporation dedicated 15 billion$ to technology development in
2013 [25]. Primary motivations: direct profit. Secondary motivations: improve brand &
corporate positioning, reduce environmental impact and ensure universal access to
energy

Financial institutions: it is the main way of funding for the great majority of companies.
They may not directly fund technology development, but expansion. They usually fund
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 45
low risk start-ups in order to grow or big companies to construct new projects. Primary
motivations: direct profit. Secondary motivations: improve brand & corporate positioning

Crowdfunding: small and newly created start-ups may use this method to obtain funding
(e.g. Wattio). It is a very small amount compared to the others funding methods. Primary
motivations: reduce environmental impact and ensure universal access to energy.
Secondary motivations: direct profit
Figure 4.3 resumes the presence of technology developers and funding institutions on the
technology curve.
Figure 4.3: Presence of developers and funding institutions in each cycle
4.3 Innovative technologies
Once seen why people/companies are innovating and who is doing it, let´s see which the result
of this innovation is. Among all the stages, those technologies in the growth stage have the
greatest potential to substitute existing technology and disrupt the electric sector. This is why
this point will focus on innovative technologies in the growth stage, mentioning also some
technologies in the emerging stage.
Innovative technologies can be classified into four groups depending on its nature: generation,
efficiency, infrastructure and storage.

Generation: it is a key activity of the electric sector. Historically, this is where more money
has been spent. The other innovative technologies try to make possible, improve or deal
with the changes brought by new generation techniques
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 46

Efficiency: it includes the technologies that enable consuming less, reducing the demand
of energy from the final consumer. So, it is closely related to the commercialization
activity of the electric sector

Infrastructure: it comprises all the technologies that improve grids: make them more
efficient and have less loses; or help monitoring and managing complex energy grids
(due to distributed generation or renewable energy) where energy does not flow in a
single direction. It is related to the transmission and distribution activities

Storage: storage units are part of the infrastructure of the electric grid. However, it is
going to be analyzed separately for two reasons: first, it is not only linked to transmission
and distribution activities, it is also related to generation and commercialization activities;
the second reason is the important role storage will play in the coming electric sector
The research of innovative technologies and companies is based on the 2013 and 2014 Global
Cleantech 100 lists [26]. Additionally, in order to find disruptive start-ups, the investment portfolio
of several energy venture capitals has also been studied (e.g. EnerTech Capital, Innogy Venture
Capital or The Westly Group). Some technological companies have also been analyzed (e.g.
Siemens, SENER and Abengoa Solar).
4.3.1 Generation
Generation technologies can be classified by their primary energy as seen in Figure 4.4:
Figure 4.4: Classification of generation technologies
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 47
a) Renewables: solar
Photovoltaic (PV):
PV technologies are usually classified into three generations, depending on the material used
and the commercial maturity.
First generation includes all the crystalline silicon technologies. It is a mature technology and it is
fully commercial nowadays. So, innovation in these technologies focuses on improving
competitiveness. These are some examples of companies innovating in this field:

Sun Edison: announced on October 2014 that they are developing a step-change
technology that will enable to deliver solar panels at a cost of $0.4 per watt peak by 2016.
The technology is called “high-pressure fluidized bed reactor” (HP-FBR) and is able to
produce high purity polysilicon ten times more efficiently than non FBR technologies

Ever Green Solar: anti-reflective glass increasing 2-3% electricity produced compared to
panels with standard glass. They also have improved performance under hot conditions
obtaining a 4% higher output

Enphase Energy: micro inverters that allow each solar module to operate independently
for a higher performance. Simple installation so that any individual could install it. Control
and monitoring system

tenkSolar: parallel architecture of reflectors capturing the light that normally falls between
rows of modules (see Figure 4.5)
Figure 4.5: Illustration of the parallel architecture [tenkSolar]

SunPower: copper foundation adding strength and becoming almost impervious to
corrosion
Since the commercial production of Si PV panels began in 1963 [27], several innovations, such
as efficiency improvement or lower manufacturing costs, have made the PV prices reduce
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 48
considerably from over 100 $/Wp to less than 1 $/Wp. This cost reduction has historically
followed a logarithmic learning curve depending on the manufactured capacity (see Figure 4.6).
In 2009, cost were higher than the theoretical learning curve due to a temporally shortage of
silicon. Then, costs came down rapidly because of Chinese dumping. They started selling solar
panels at very low prices. In 2013, the European Commission carried an investigation to decide
if Chinese PV producers were selling panels below their manufacturing costs in order to
eliminate European competitors. The 2nd December 2013, the investigation concluded that China
was making dumping and some duties were imposed to those PV panels imported from China
[28]. The price increase in 2009 and the next fast price reduction had their origin in events taking
place in that moment and did not mean a structural change of the industry. So, in the long term
costs will tend to the theoretical curve. Sun Edison´s announcement, however, would mean a
structural reduction of costs if it came true, leading to a different learning curve model.
Figure 4.6: Learning curve for module price as function of the cumulative PV module shipments [based on ITR PV
2013 Results]
Second generation technologies are mainly thin-films. These technologies are in the transition to
be commercial after a long period of development. Thin-films are built by successive thin layers
deposited on a glass substrate, requiring lot less semiconductor than Si panels. So, thin-films
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 49
could potentially provide cheaper electricity than conventional Si modules due to lower cost per
kW, but they have lower efficiencies making them lose competitiveness. In addition, they are
light and flexible which enables creating new functionalities for solar PV, as building-integrated
PV (BIPV). BIPV are used to replace conventional building materials of the outside surface of a
building. Thin-films innovation is focused in finding ways of improving cell efficiencies.
Historically, this innovation has mainly come by the development of cells with different
semiconducting materials. There are mainly three types of thin-film commercially available:

Amorphous silicon, a-Si (e.g. Xunlight Corporation, Anwell technologies): the most
developed and known thin-film technology along with Cadmium telluride. It has
efficiencies in the range of 4% to 8%. The main disadvantage of this technology is that
the sun degrades its performance over time

Cadmium Telluride, CdTe (e.g. First Solar): have lower production costs and higher
efficiencies than other thin-film technologies, up to 16.7%. The main disadvantage is that
tellurium production in the long-term may be limited

Copper-Indium-Selenide/Copper-Indium-Gallium-Diselenide,
CIS/CIGS
(e.g.
Ascent
Solar, Solar Frontier): have the highest efficiencies among all the thin-film technologies.
Nowadays, it goes from 7% to 16%. However, efficiencies up to 20% have been achieved
in laboratories
Amorphous silicon has historically dominated the thin-film industry, as it was the only technology
commercially available. Since 2004, CdTe technology became increasingly important, and it
reached market shares around 70% in 2009. Finally, CIGS are gaining market share since 2009,
and in 2013, they almost reached CdTe technology (see Figure 4.7).
Figure 4.7: Thin-film market share by type [“Photovoltaics Report”, Fraunhofer ISE – Oct. 2014]
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 50
Finally, the third generation includes concentrating PV (CPV), organic solar cells, dye-sensitized
solar cells (DSSC) and other emerging technologies. Some of these technologies are starting to
be commercialized (mainly CPV) and the rest are still in development.
CPV are based in the use of optical devices (i.e. mirror and lenses) to concentrate direct solar
radiation into a small solar cell. This cell is composed by a multi-junction which makes it highly
efficient. This technology is classified into three groups depending on the solar concentration.
First, low concentration PV having concentrations in the range of 2 to 100 suns. Then, medium
concentration PV from 100 to 300 suns. And finally, high concentration PV with concentrations
up to 1,000 suns. Nowadays, efficiencies are around 35%, but have reached the 40% in some
laboratory proves. The main disadvantage is that they work under direct solar irradiance,
meaning that the sun has to be directly hitting the panel, not as in the case of silicon PV, where
diffuse radiation also generates energy. So, having solar tracking systems is almost necessary
for these technologies. Moreover, although the amount of semiconductor material used is
reduced considerably, the optical devices are usually expensive, making them more expensive
than silicon PV. Big efforts in innovation are being made to reduce the optics costs. Some of the
companies innovating and offering CPV technology are Soitec, Suncore Photovoltaic
technology, Zytech and Abengoa Solar.
Organic cells are those composed by organic or polymer materials. It is a really young
technology. Organic cells are usually cheap, but they have very low efficiencies, in the range of
4% to 5%. Heliatek obtained efficiencies around 10% in 2012 and aims increasing them to
almost 14% by 2015. Organic cells are light and flexible. It is a niche technology that could
compete in the future with other PV technologies for portable applications (e.g. mobile phones,
laptops, toys). Innovation consists mainly on searching new material with higher efficiencies and
better properties.
The following table compares some performance characteristics of each of the PV technologies:
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 51
Table 4.1: Characteristic comparison of main PV technologies [based on “Renewable energy technologies: cost
analysis series, Solar Photovoltaics”, IRENA – June 2012]
Among all these technologies, Si PV is nowadays the leading technology (i.e. ~90% of PV
market share in 2013) and seems to remain as it is for a long while (i.e. since 1992 silicon
technology has accounted of market shares in the range of 80-90%, and has an increasing
tendency). They have the better trade between costs and efficiency, making them the most
competitive technology. Moreover, if the manufacturing process that Sun Edison has announced
becomes true, costs will reduce significantly. Other technologies, like CPV or BIPV, have some
drawbacks against silicon PV making them occupy a secondary place in the future. BIPV´s
expansion is mostly limited to the construction of new buildings in locations with good sun
conditions (i.e. facing south, not being shaded by other buildings). Moreover, BIPV results being
quite expensive, it may be cheaper in many cases to construct the building with common
materials and then installing the solar panels in the rooftop. CPV technology´s main
disadvantage is that they only work over direct normal irradiance (DNI). This means that
electricity generation could go to 0 if a cloud is shading the sun. So, they are only competitive in
places with high yearly DNI (e.g. Australia, Middle East, Northern and Southern Africa). And as
the cost of the optical devices is quite high, they have slightly higher LCOE and could only
replace silicon PV in applications with limited space where space has more relevance than
economics.
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 52
Figure 4.8: Market share by PV technology [“Photovoltaics Report”, Fraunhofer ISE – Oct. 2014]
Concentrated Solar Power (CSP):
There are four main types of CSP technologies. Table 4.2 shows the main characteristics of
each technology:
Table 4.2: Comparison of different CSP technologies [based on “Renewable energy technologies: cost analysis
series, Concentrating Solar Power”, IRENA – June 2012]]
Innovation efforts in CSP technologies are mainly done in four fields: solar collection system,
thermal generation system, storage system and electrical generation system (see Table 4.3).
Thermal generation system is where higher improvements of efficiency and cost can be
obtained. As a consequence, the bigger efforts are being done in this field, especially in
obtaining higher operating temperatures.
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 53
Table 4.3: Innovation focuses by technology and field [A.T. Kearney experience]
Between the different companies researching in this field, Abengoa Solar is a good
representative as they are trying to solve the temperature limitation with different solutions.
Other companies such as Solar Reserve, SENER, Bright Source and Solar Millennium are also
developing these technologies, but just the Abengoa´s case is going to be shown in order to
avoid repetitions.
Abengoa Solar is developing technologies mainly in two solar thermal technologies:
concentrated solar tower and parabolic trough. The developed tower technologies are the
followings:

Superheated tower: the company´s biggest efforts in R&D in recent years have focused
on designing a new generation of solar tower. They have built a 3 MW prototype at the
Solucar platform that has achieved producing superheated steam at high temperatures
significantly improving power generation efficiency

Salt solar tower: solar tower where molten salts are used as heat transfer fluid

Solugas: Abengoa has begun the construction of a pilot plant that seeks to validate a new
energy generation concept that combines solar energy with a Brayton cycle. This
technology uses air as the heat transfer fluid. High cycle temperatures can be reached
achieving high power generation efficiency
While the parabolic trough developments are:

High temperatures: advanced heat transfer fluids that operate at a higher temperature
than present fluids, increasing the efficiency of the cycle. Certain molten salts are
currently being evaluated. They could increase the operation temperature up to 500ºC
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 54

Direct steam generation: eliminates the need for an intermediate heat transfer fluid, being
water directly going in the troughs. The main advantage of this technology is that
eliminates the maximum temperature limitations, thus increasing system efficiency
Solar tower technology seems to be the technology that is likely to dominate the CSP market.
The main reason for this is the LCOE comparison between both. As the following table shows,
solar tower had lower LCOE in 2011 and predictions are that it will not change for 2020.
Parabolic trough LCOE is predicted to be around 0.09 and 0.14 USD/kWh, while solar tower´s
LCOE is likely to be slightly lower, 0.07-0.09 USD/kWh.
Table 4.4: Estimated LCOE for parabolic trough and solar tower technologies [based on “Renewable energy
technologies: cost analysis series, Concentrating Solar Power”, IRENA – June 2012]
Finally, when comparing solar PV technologies with CSP technologies, it seems that PV will
have larger expansion in the future due to three main reasons:

CSP technologies only work under direct normal irradiation, while PV technologies also
produce energy with diffuse radiation. So, concentrated solar thermal technologies are
mainly limited to location with high DNI

PV has the characteristic of modularity and scalability, allowing it to distributed
generation. Solar thermal technologies, however, are limited to utility scale generation

PV has lower LCOE predictions (see Figure 4.9)
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 55
Figure 4.9: LCOE evolution for solar technologies [“Levelized cost of electricity renewable energy technologies”,
Fraunhofer ISE – Nov. 2013]
b) Renewables: Wind
Wind energy technologies have traditionally been classified into two groups: onshore and
offshore wind. However, there is an additional emerging group: high altitude wind power.
Onshore wind is a mature and widely deployed technology (i.e. ~110 GW capacity in Europe by
2013 [29]). Offshore wind is an emerging technology of which there are already some projects
being carried out (i.e. almost 7 GW of cumulative capacity in Europe by 2013). High altitude wind
power, on the contrary, is an industry that has just emerged and is on early phases of
development, with no commercial solutions already installed. This maturity difference between
the three technologies leads to different types of innovation. While onshore wind main
developments are in the field of improving efficiency, high altitude wind power´s innovations are
new and creative ways of generating electricity.
Onshore
Innovation in the onshore wind industry has taken two main directions. On one hand, making the
turbines bigger and more powerful. The first wind turbine was made by Bonus Energy and had a
capacity of 22 kW. Nowadays, biggest onshore wind turbines have capacities around 3 MW and
offshore turbines reach the 8 MW. Nevertheless, the use of big turbines in onshore wind farms is
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 56
limited by logistics. As the turbine has larger capacities, its size increases (e.g. Siemens´s larger
onshore turbine has a capacity of 3.3 MW and a blade length of 63 m). They are reaching some
dimensions that it is becoming increasingly difficult to transport turbines to the site (e.g. large
trucks with extensions or necessity to build extra-wide roads). There are innovative solutions
appearing to deal with these installation problems. Skyacht Aircraft Inc. is developing a tethered
aerostat crane that would end with those difficulties and enable the deployment of bigger
turbines.
On the other hand, improving reliability and efficiency is the second direction of innovation. The
followings are some examples:

Direct drive (Enercon): this technology is based on a simple principle: fewer rotating
components reduce mechanical stress allowing an increasing of the equipment´s
technical life. One large O&M cost of a wind farm is caused by gearbox failures. The
gearbox is the element connecting the rotor with the generator. Usually, the rotor and the
generator work at different rotation frequencies. The rotor rotation speed is given by wind
and it is usually of a few Hz. The generator frequency, on the contrary, is given by the
electrical frequency of the grid, 50Hz or 60Hz depending on the continent. So, gears are
the responsible for converting the low frequency of the rotor to the required one by the
generator. In direct drive systems, the rotor and the generator are directly interconnected
to form one gearless unit. However, the frequency of the generated electricity has then to
be adapted to grid frequency by power electronics

Superconductivity (AML): it is based on generators having superconductive wires. These
generators are 75% lighter, 50% smaller, more efficient and more reliable than current
generators

Air core generators (Boulder Wind Power): the air core generators developed by this
company are lighter, cost less and deliver more electricity

Variable speed control (Atlantic Bearing Services, ChapDrive…): originally, wind turbines
were fixed speed turbines, this is, the rotor frequency was the same for all wind speeds.
This meant that the wind turbine was not working at peak efficiency across all wind
speeds. This mechanism allows the rotor moving at different frequencies depending on
the wind speed, increasing the efficiency and the output energy
Onshore wind is a mature technology, already competitive with conventional generation
technologies (see Figure 4.10) but not further significant cost improvements are expected. The
Fraunhofer´s study in November 2013 stated that the LCOE of offshore wind was in the range of
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 57
0.045 €/kWh to 0.11 €/kWh, while 2030 predictions are between 0.04 €/kWh to 0.10 €/kWh.
Moreover, best wind locations are already being used. So, onshore wind expansion has to be
done in locations with worse wind conditions. Another option that some wind farm operators are
taking into account is rebuilding the old wind farms (those with best wind conditions, as these
were the first to be used) and replace the old small turbine for some current larger turbines.
Figure 4.10: Wind, Coal and CCGT LCOE comparison [based on “Levelized cost of electricity renewable energy
technologies”, Fraunhofer ISE – Nov. 2013]
Offshore
Offshore wind industry development has taken two main directions: having larger and powerful
turbines and going further from the shore. Larger turbines mainly bring cost reductions, while
distancing from shore enables taking advantage of more stable and powerful winds. However,
the further from the shore, the deeper the seafloor usually is. Substructures are evolving fast in
order to deal with the increasing depth. Industry development is explained in greater depth in
point 7.3.
Offshore wind is an industry that is predicted to have relevant cost reduction, leading to an
improvement of the LCOE. Fraunhofer´s study in November 2013 calculated that LCOE was in
the range of 0.12-0.195 €/kWh in 2013 and the predictions are improvements until 0.095-0.15
€/kWh in 2030.
High altitude wind power
Wind is stronger and has higher speed as the altitude increases. Wind speed can be estimated
as a function of the altitude as:
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 58
Where Hr is the reference altitude, Vr is the wind speed at the altitude of reference, H is the new
altitude, V the speed at the new altitude and Sf an experimental factor that depends on the type
of location. For example, if the wind speed is 4 m/s at 10 m altitude on a location with Sf = 0.31,
the wind speed at 50 m can be estimated to be 6.59 m/s.
High altitude wind power technologies try to take advantage of this effect by working at altitudes
above 500m. There are two kind of high altitude wind generators in development nowadays:
aerostats and gliders.

Aerostat: Altaeros energy is the company developing this solution. It consists on placing
a wind turbine in the middle of an aerostat. The aerostat flies at hundreds of meters of
altitude and is connected to ground by some tethers. When meteorological conditions are
not good enough, the aerostat is taken to ground. It can be easily moved from one site to
another as the ground station consists on a truck
Figure 4.11: Picture of the aerostat of Altaeros Energy
The main advantage of this aerostat is its flexibility, mobility and rapid deployment. It
eliminates the logistical challenge of installing traditional renewables in remote areas. In
this case, the truck has to go to the desired location and then the aerostat is released,
reducing considerably the cost of energy in remote areas

Gliders: it consists on kites or airplanes gliding at high altitudes. There are two types of
gliders: those with wind turbine generators and those that generate energy unrolling a
cable. Makani power builds a solution of the first kind. It consists on an airplane that has
some turbines on it. As it glides at high altitude winds, energy is generated and
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 59
transmitted through the cable that joins the ground station and the plane. The other types
of gliders generate power by unrolling a cable. There is a kite or an airplane connected to
a turbine in ground. Wind pushes them to higher altitudes, making the turbine rotate as
the cable unrolls. Once the cable is totally unrolled, the kite is placed in a special position
to reduce the energy spend during the recovery process. Skysails Power, KiteGen and
Ampyx Power are some companies offering these solutions
Figure 4.12: Illustration of Makani´s plane (left) and picture of KiteGen´s kite (right)
Figure 4.13: Illustration of the working principle of Ampyx Power´s technology
Figure 4.14: Illustration of a wind farm with Skysails technology
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 60
Overall, high altitude wind solutions are in early stages of development and their expansion will
depend on their reliability and cost evolution. However, there is one thing that seems to be
already clear: they are the fastest way to build a power generation plant. It makes them
adequate for some niche application. For example, if an earthquake leaved the electric system
of a region inoperable, aerostats would be easily installed and power supply would be recovered
quickly. Another example could be the case of an oil well. These technologies could easily
replace the diesel generators used to produce the required power.
c) Renewables: Geothermal
In the geothermal industry, innovation goes on the direction of modularity and being able to
produce energy without the need of special geological conditions. In this field, there are two
companies with innovative solutions:

Green Energy Group: they have created a modular solution of 6.4 MW with the size of a
40 foot ISO container. The aim of this solution is to end with the prohibited investment
cost associated with the deployment of traditional geothermal power plants. It is based in
the standardization of key components for obtaining cost reductions. Moreover, these
power plants are designed to be decommissioned, transported and redeployed in a
second well, optimizing their profitability

Ecoforest: this Spanish company offers a solution that can be installed anywhere without
the need of specific geological conditions. The idea is that below 20m of depth,
temperature keeps almost constant all over the year. This solution has a reverse heat
pump that uses the constant temperature to heat water independently of the season. It is
oriented to replace heating systems in locations without access to natural gas, where
heating is done by diesel generators or using electricity
Geothermal energy is likely to have little expansion in the future. Although they could reduce
their cost and become highly competitive against other technologies, they are limited to those
places with the required geothermal characteristics. And solutions that do not have this
limitation, as the offered by Ecoforest, are usually niche technologies.
d) Renewables: Ocean energy
It is an emerging technology, so innovation consists on finding creative and efficient ways of
harvesting ocean energy. These are some of the innovative solutions developed:

Wave Dragon: it is a floating energy converter of the overtopping type that can be
deployed in a single unit or in arrays. It basically consists of two wave reflectors focusing
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 61
waves towards a ramp. Behind the ramp there is a large reservoir where the water is
stored temporarily. This water is evacuated through hydro turbines that use the difference
of the potential energy between the reservoir and the sea level

Pelamis: the solution offered by this company uses the wave motion to generate
electricity. It is formed by five semi-submerged tube sections that are facing into the
direction of the waves. As the waves pass through, it bends converting this movement
into electricity
Figure 4.15: Illustration of Pelamis´ wave motion generator

AWS and Oceanlinx: these two companies offer similar solution based in wave generated
air compression. The solution offered has three main components. First, an oscillating
water column. It is a simple construction that works as a piston and a cylinder as waves
pass through. Second, a bidirectional reaction turbine that generates electricity
regardless the direction the wind is flowing. So, electricity is generated during both steps
of the cycle: compression and decompression. And finally, the generator that converts
the rotation of the turbine into electricity
Figure 4.16: Structure of wave generated air compression

Ocean Power Technologies: this solution consists on a buoy that converts wave energy
into electricity. This buoy is anchored to the seafloor. As waves pass through, a piston
inside the buoy bobs. This movement drives a generator producing electricity
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 62
Figure 4.17: Illustration of a buoy generator
Ocean energy is an emerging industry in early phases of development. The firsts real scale
prototypes are being build and tested currently. Technologies are usually not price competitive.
The LCOE estimated by the UK government in 2014 (see chapter 7) is £305/MWh, significantly
higher than other renewable technologies as onshore or offshore wind, £90/MWh and
£140/MWh respectively. The LCOE is likely to improve as technology develops, but is unlikely
that in the mid-term they reduce the large gap they have with other more mature generation
techniques.
e) Conventional generation: Fossil fuels
Fossil fuels are a relevant part of the generation mix because they allow balancing the
intermittency of renewable energy and the inflexibility of base load units. As a consequence,
current projections for global energy demand still point to fossil fuels being used in quantities
incompatible with level required to stabilize greenhouse emissions. In 2011, worldwide fossil fuel
consumption was 10,668 Mtoe emitting 31.2 Gt of CO2. Predictions for 2035 in the New Policies
Scenario [30] are 13,208 Mtoe and 37.2 Gt of CO2 emissions. Carbon Capture and Storage
(CCS) is the only way to reduce CO2 emissions while keeping fossil fuels in the generation mix.
CCS is a family of technologies and techniques that enable the capture of CO 2 from fuel
combustion or industrial processes, the transport of CO2 via ships or pipelines, and its
underground storage in depleted oil and gas fields and deep saline formations [31].
In October 2014, the first commercial power plant with CCS was launched [32]. It is a coal plant,
called Boundary Dam, located in Saskatchewan, Canada. Right now only two other CCS power
plant projects are under construction, both in the USA. CCS is still a very costly technology. The
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 63
company operating the Boundary Dam coal plant, SaskPower, invested $1 billion to equip one of
the four generators of the coal plant with CCS. Moreover, the output capacity was reduced about
a 20% from the original 160 MW. Nevertheless, CCS should get more competitive over time.
The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change projects that the price of adding CCS to coal
plants should reduce to one-third of what SaskPower spent at Boundary Dam. Additionally,
SaskPower states that with the lessons learned so far, it could now build a similar CCS project
for $200 million less.
Nowadays, adding CCS is not profitable and it needs from government support in order to be
deployed.
f) Conventional generation: Nuclear energy
Development in nuclear fission energy is coming from the Generation IV International Forum
(GIF) [33]. It is an international collective representing governments of 13 countries and it was
initiated in year 2000. They are developing six nuclear reactor technologies for deployment
between 2020 and 2030. Four of them are fast neutron reactors and all operate at higher
temperatures than today´s reactors. The six technologies are: gas-cooled fast reactors, leadcooled fast reactors, molten salt reactors (there are two variants), sodium-cooled fast reactors,
supercritical water-cooled reactors and very high-temperature gas reactors. Table 4.5 shows the
main characteristics of each of the technologies.
Table 4.5 : Characteristics of the six nuclear reactor technologies [GIF]
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 64
Apart from nuclear fission development, there are also some R&D efforts focused on nuclear
fusion. ITER is a large-scale scientific experiment that aims to demonstrate the technological
and scientific feasibility of fusion energy. It aims to be the first of all fusion experiments to
produce more energy than the one consumed, having an input power of 50 MW and a
production of 500 MW. The ITER project is being developed by seven international agencies:
China, European Union, India, Japan, Korea, Russia and United States. The construction works
began in 2010 near Marseille, France. Plans are to end construction by 2019 and start producing
energy by the end of 2020s.
In October 2014, the aerospace company Lockheed Martin claimed to be developing a compact
fusion reactor [34]. The first reactor prototype will be designed to generate around 100 MW and
fit into transportable unit measuring 23x43 ft (e.g. a truck).
4.3.2 Storage
The performance of a storage device can be defined by the following parameters:

Rated power (kW): the maximum power that a storage system is able to give

Energy capacity (kWh): the amount of energy that can be stored

Discharge time (seconds, minutes, hours…): how long the storage device is able to
supply the rated power. Energy capacity can be calculated as the product of the rated
power and discharge time

Response time (seconds, minutes, hours…): the time needed to start providing the
demanded energy

Roundtrip efficiency (%): the ratio between the energy discharged and the energy needed
to charge it. It is a measure of the energy losses for each cycle

Lifetime (years, cycles): how long the storage device will work without significant
performance degradation

Energy density (kWh/kg) and power density (kW/kg): relation between storage and
physical characteristics
Energy storage devices have plenty of uses, from reliability purposes (e.g. back-up power
generation in case of grid failure) to renewable integration. Each of these applications has its
own requirements of power and energy. For instance, a back-up storage device needs a few kW
in order to maintain the supply of a house or an office, and energy should last from some
minutes to a few hours. Renewable integration, in the contrary, needs power capacities in the
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 65
order of the MW and last for some hours. Figure 4.18 shows the power and energy requirements
for some of the most common storage applications. It also shows to which segment of the
electric sector the application corresponds.
Figure 4.18: Requirements of each storage application [“Electricity Energy Storage Technology Options”, EPRI –
Dec. 2010]
Energy is not usually stored as electricity; it is first transformed into another energy form and
then stored. Storage devices can be classified depending on the form in which energy is stored:
chemical, electrochemical, mechanical and thermal storage. Pumped hydro storage (a type of
mechanical storage) is the most mature and expanded technology between storage devices,
around the 95% of current storage capacity [35]. As it is a very mature technology, there are not
many innovative solutions for it and it is not going to be analyzed in this chapter.
a) Chemical energy storage
Hydrogen is the main technology of chemical storage. It follows a three step process:

Production: there are different ways of generating hydrogen molecules, but water
electrolysis is the one using electricity. It consists on splitting the water molecule to
separate hydrogen from oxygen (2H2O + electricity -> 2H2 + O2)

Storage: as Figure 4.19 shows, hydrogen has good energy properties by mass compared
to other fuels, but it has poor volumetric properties. At standard conditions, hydrogen is in
the gaseous state and is the gas with the lowest density. So, one of the main problem of
hydrogen is the space that it takes to be stored, needing high pressures to reach
reasonable volumes (e.g. density of 42 kgH2/m3 at 700 bar). Moreover, strong safety
measures have to been taken due to hydrogen´s inflammability in the gaseous state
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 66
Figure 4.19: Energy densities for different fuels

Electricity generation: done by fuel cells. It is the opposite chemical process to
electrolysis in which hydrogen and oxygen are joined together forming water again,
generating electricity in this process
There are many companies that, believing hydrogen will be the main storage method in the
future, are developing innovative hydrogen technologies. These are some of those companies
and their solutions:

McPhy energy: they have developed a solid state hydrogen storage. Some metals or
alloys have the property of forming reversible bonds with hydrogen atoms leading to the
formation of metal hydride. By using different temperatures and low pressures, hydrogen
is either absorbed or desorbed by the metal. McPhy has selected magnesium hydrides
(MgH2) for mass storage. Solid state storage main advantage is the higher volume
density than compressed gas or liquid hydrogen (see Figure 4.20). This technology also
reduces drastically the risk of inflammation
Figure 4.20: Energy density of hydrogen in different states [McPhy energy]
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 67

Hydrexia: this company offers a similar solution to McPhy energy, a solid state hydrogen
storage using magnesium hydrides

Areva: it has developed the Greenergy Box. It is a device consisting of an electrolyzer
and a fuel cell. It stores hydrogen and oxygen generated by water electrolysis and then
recombines them to generate electricity. This solution is already being implemented in
different locations, Corsica and the French city of La Croix Valmer between them

École Polytechnique Fédérale de Lausanne (EPFL): a scientist group of this university
has created a solution for transforming hydrogen in a less flammable liquid fuel, formic
acid. It is yet a technology in early developments. It uses CO 2 to create formic acid by its
hydrogenation
Figure 4.21: Cycle of hydrogen storage as formic acid [EPFL]
Hydrogen has some very good properties: it has a good energy density compared to other fuels;
it can be generated in one site and transported to another; it can be used as a transport fuel; it is
an endless and environmental friendly resource and the cost of the hydrogen is very low due to
its abundance. However, there are some features that slow down its expansion. It has very low
roundtrip efficiencies (20-50%) as each of the stages has energy losses. Efficiency of water
electrolysis is in the range of 60-80%, while fuel cells have efficiencies around 50%. Moreover,
as it has to be stored under high pressure, large quantities of energy have to be used, losing
efficiency in storage.
In the case of transport, hydrogen vehicles sound as possible substitutes of combustion engines.
But, they will be competing with electric vehicles and these last seem to be currently in a better
position. Electric vehicles´ price is going down fast carried by batteries´ cost reduction.
Moreover, the energy cycle has better efficiencies and they are easier to charge nowadays.
Nevertheless, some think that this will be the main storage method in the future. The property of
easy transportation makes it have different applications, such as, cars functioning with hydrogen
and emitting water instead of CO2 or each household being supplied hydrogen at home by using
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 68
the current gas distribution grid and generating electricity with a fuel cell. The large power and
energy capacities make hydrogen a good solution for renewable integration too. Hydrogen could
have many new applications if roundtrip efficiencies were improved and its storage was
simplified. Among those who think in a hydrogen future, Shell, Siemens and The Linde Group
are some of the remarkable companies.
b) Electrochemical energy storage
There are two main types of electrochemical energy storage technologies: batteries and ultracapacitors.
Batteries
They can be classified into two groups depending on how energy is stored. Solid state batteries
are the first type. These are the batteries that have been used historically and store the energy
in the electrodes, while the electrolyte allows the ions move between electrodes. There are
many types of solid state batteries: Pb acid and Nickel-Cadmium (NiCd) batteries are the
conventional technologies; and lithium ion (Li-ion), sodium sulfur (NaS), NaNiCl and lead
batteries are the most common new technologies.
The second group is formed by flow batteries. They store the energy in the electrolyte, having as
one of the biggest advantages that they can be almost instantly recharged by replacing the
electrolyte liquid. Redox, Iron-Chromium, Vanadium Redox and Zinc-Bromine are the main flow
battery technologies.
The followings are some examples of companies developing some innovative technologies in
the world of batteries:

Ambri: the solution offered by this company, liquid metal battery, is the only battery where
all three active components are in liquid form when the battery operates. The two liquid
electrodes are separated by a molten salt electrolyte, and these liquid layers float on top
of each other based on density differences and immiscibility. The main advantage is the
low cost, obtained by the use of inexpensive, earth-abundant materials and the design
that takes advantage of the economies of scale inherent to electro-metallurgy and
conventional manufacturing. Their actual prototype is a 17.5 kW / 35 kWh battery and
they intend building systems of 1 MW / 2MWh

Aquion energy: this company has developed the Aqueous Hybrid Ion battery, a saltwater
electrolyte technology. It uses abundant and nontoxic materials. This technology was
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 69
developed with one clear idea: a large-scale energy storage system that is high
performance, safe, sustainable and cost-effective. They offer modules with output powers
from the few kilowatts to multi-MW. The batteries are large and operate slowly, but they
are manufactured economically

EOS energy storage: they offer a zinc hybrid cathode battery. It has a cost of $160/kWh,
lifetime over 30 years and 75% round-trip efficiency. Moreover, it has an energy capacity
of 6 MWh housed in a 40 feet ISO container. The company claims it can offer a LCOE of
$0.12/kWh [36]
Batteries main advantages are modularity and high efficiency (70-100% in advanced batteries).
Nowadays, the main application areas are portable devices and electric vehicles. It is also used
as back-up storage for households or offices. However, their high costs make them unprofitable
in utility scale deployment for the moment.
Batteries outlook seems promising. Tesla is building a giga factory of batteries in Nevada. The
predictions are that it will produce batteries for 500,000 vehicles by 2020, reducing the kWh
price of batteries by 30% [37]. This will mean a step forward for batteries expansion in many
aspects. First, electric vehicles prices would reduce significantly as batteries are their main cost.
It will also launch the distributed generation expansion. Economic batteries will increase
profitability of these installations by allowing storage during day and consumption at evening and
night. For instance, the LCOE for residential solar-plus-battery installations is already better than
retail energy prices in Hawaii and it is likely to be the case in New York from 2025 and California
from 2031 [38]. In addition, the deployment at utility scale could become profitable, helping to
deal with renewables intermittency and their integration.
Ultra-capacitors/supercapacitors
They are high capacitance electrochemical condensers based on a thin, layered solid/liquid
interface created by special, high-surface (1000 m2/g) carbon electrodes and electrolytes. The
main characteristics of ultra-capacitors are the high power density (up to 6 kW/kg), a low specific
energy (30 Wh/kg) and fast response time [39]. Moreover, high power density and low specific
energy result on fast charging and discharging rates.
One of the main uses for ultra-capacitors is transport. Their high power density and fast
response time characteristics make them ideal for supplying power during the acceleration of
electric vehicles. These are some examples of ultra-capacitors being used in transport
applications:
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 70

Electric bus: the first electric bus in Spain, developed and fabricated by Irizar, started
working in the summer of 2014 in San Sebastian [40]

Supercapacitor tram: the Chinese city of Guangzhou is the first city in the world to have a
tram powered solely by supercapacitors, without the need of overhead wires. The tram is
charged as needed at stops. This process takes between 10 and 30 seconds and the
trams are able to run for up to about two and a half miles between charges [41]
They could also be used in applications with high power and low energy requirement, such as
grid frequency regulation.
c) Mechanical energy storage
There are two main storage mechanisms apart from pumped hydro storage: Compressed Air
Energy Storage (CAES) and flywheels.
CAES
It consists on using off-peak electricity to compress and store air into underground caverns or
mines. Pressurized air is then used in a gas turbine when it is required. Common gas turbines
usually use 2/3 of the input fuel to compress air before combustion. So, using already
compressed and stored air, input fuel can be reduced by a 40%. Efficiencies in the range of 42%
to 55% are obtained [42].
The preferable locations are salt caverns. They have several positive characteristic for storing
compressed air (e.g. high flexibility, no pressure losses within storage no reaction with the
oxygen in the air). However, in the case of no suitable salt formations, natural aquifers or
depleted natural gas fields could be used.
The main problem of CAES is that during compression air is heated up strongly and the energy
needed for compression increases with air temperature. So, air has to be cooled during the
compression process and then heated again before the combustion in the gas turbine. Efficiency
could be improved storing the thermal energy obtained during the air cooling and using it during
the re-heating. Efficiencies up to 70% can be achieved. This technology is called adiabatic
method. It is under development, mainly driven by an international consortium headed by the
company RWE. A pilot plant is scheduled to start working by 2018. There are two other
companies that are also developing adiabatic solutions:

Airlight Energy: they use a thermal energy storage that they had already developed for
CSP. Instead of using underground salt caverns, they use mountains which enable easy
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 71
access in order to construct inside the air storage reservoir. Furthermore, equipment
such as the turbo machinery is also placed inside the mountain, reducing dramatically the
visibility and environmental footprint of the plant. This solution obtains round-trip
efficiencies of >72%

LightSail Energy: they are developing a flexible and modular energy storage solution. Air
is stored in tanks and each of the modules has a 250 kW output power and 750 kWh
storage capacity. Roundtrip efficiencies are around 90%
The potential use of compressed air is similar to the one of pumped hydro storage due to the
similar characteristics of output power and energy storage capacity; applications that require
high power and large amounts of energy, such as, renewable integration.
Liquid Air Energy Storage (LAES) works similar to CAES, but in this case, instead of
compressing the air, it is refrigerated to temperatures around -200ºC and turns liquid. In the
liquid state, air can be stored in standard insulated, but unpressurised vessels at very large
scale. Highview Power offers a LAES storage solution. They are developing systems of 50 MW
output power and 200 MWh of energy, having efficiencies around 70%.
Flywheel
It works by accelerating a rotor. The rotor spins in a nearly frictionless enclosure and operates in
vacuum in order to reduce drag and maintain efficiency. Low-speed flywheels rotate at rates up
to 10,000 RPM and more advanced ones can reach a rotational frequency of 100,000 RPM [43].
The main characteristics of flywheels are the high power density and fast response time (see
Table 4.6). Moreover, they have good round-trip efficiencies, but usually have low energy
density. As a consequence, flywheels are increasingly important to high power and low energy
applications. They are especially appropriate for applications of power quality and reliability,
being the responsible for frequency regulation. When there is a relatively big change in energy
demand or supply in a short period of time (a power plant is switched on/off), the frequency of
the grid is slightly changed from 50 Hz. Flywheels are a good option to absorb the excess power
or supply the lack of power in this short periods, maintaining grid frequency close to 50 Hz. This
is especially important in small electric systems (e.g. Canarias islands), where a power plant
produces a higher proportion of the total power than in a bigger system (e.g. Iberian peninsula).
Electric vehicles could be another application of flywheels. During acceleration, these vehicles
need high powers during short periods of time. A fast response time is also essential. However,
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 72
space is usually reduced in vehicles, becoming the main limitation for flywheels. Ultra-capacitors
seem to be winning in this application.
The biggest company offering flywheels is Beacon Power. They produce carbon fiber flywheels
of powers going from 100 kW to multi-MW.
d) Thermal energy storage
It allows storing energy in the form of heat or cold. Molten salts are the main current commercial
technology. These salts have the property to absorb and store heat energy with very few losses.
The use of this storage technology has almost exclusively been by CSP power plants, as these
power plants first produce heat to then generate electricity. So, they can directly store the
thermal energy before its transformation to electricity. The largest efforts on developing thermal
storage come then from CSP developers and operators. For instance, this is one of the four
main focuses of Abengoa Solar R&D efforts.
There is a thermal storage technology that allows converting electricity to thermal energy and
stored it, Pumped Heat Electrical Storage (PHES). Electricity is used to drive a storage engine
connected to two large thermal stores. In the energy storing step, electrical energy drives a heat
pump, which moves heat from the cold store to the hot store. To generate electricity back, the
heat pump is reversed and becomes a heat engine. It takes heat from the hot store, delivers
waste to the cold store and produces mechanical work [44]. One company offering this solution
is Isentropic, which has a PHES solution with round-trip efficiencies around 70-75% and a
lifetime over 25 years [45]. Tthey calculate to have a levelized cost of storage of $50/MWh [46].
To sum up, Table 4.6 resumes the main characteristics of the different storage technologies:
Table 4.6: Overview of main characteristics by storage technology [based on “The future role and challenges of
Energy Storage “, European Commission]
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 73
4.3.3 Efficiency
Efficiency technologies can be classified into three groups depending on its functionality:
performance efficiency, monitoring and management and building materials.

Performance efficiency: It comprises all the technologies, which having similar
characteristics and performance, need less power to work

Monitoring and management: technologies that help tracking the consumption in a house
and consequently, allow changing habits to reduce consumption

Building materials: those technologies that allow constructing more efficient buildings,
reducing the energy requirements
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 74
Table 4.7: Sample of relevant energy efficiency start-ups
Regulation plays an important role in this industry. As technology develops, governments
introduce the new efficiency solutions into regulation. For instance, the RD 235/2013 introduced
in Spain the minimum requirements of energy efficiency for buildings, or the electro-domestics´
energy certification introduced by the European Union. So, there is no doubt that efficiency
technologies will be adopted progressively at a relative high speed.
In the case of performance efficiency technologies, the absorption pace will be mostly
determined by the average life of lighting and electro-domestics. Although there are currently
more efficient technologies being commercialized, the change will mainly happen when the need
of buying new one comes. A similar thing happens with building materials, the change will mostly
come from new buildings, which are forced by law fulfilling some efficiency requirements. These
obligations of efficiency are less strict to already existing buildings. So, even if they will also
gradually adopt these technologies, pace will be slower. Finally, monitoring and management
technologies are likely to have a slower adoption as they usually imply habits changes in people.
Efficiency has mainly two effects in the power sector. First, it seems obvious that energy
consumption is reduced. Although this being true, efficiency can change people´s habits leading
to greater energy consumption. For instance, as heating or lighting are more efficient than
previous technologies, people may use them for longer time without worrying of an expensive
bill. In the meantime, a management application, as the one offered by Wattio, that lets you
control lighting and electro-domestic from the mobile phone creates new possibilities that may
increase consumption. For example, someone could switch on the heating remotely from the
office to have a warm arrival to home or switch on lights and the music player while he is on
holidays to simulate life and chased robbers away. So, the energy consumption reduction may
not be proportional to the efficiency improvement.
The other effect is load shift. Home monitoring and management devices make easier to adapt
some consumption habits to periods were electricity is cheaper. For example, in the case of
electricity price being the half at night that during the day, someone could program an
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 75
application (e.g. Wattio) to switch on the dish washer or the washing machine at night. Or in the
case of having a self-consumption PV module, electro-domestics could be activated during the
mid-day, maximizing the consumption of the energy generated.
4.3.4 Infrastructure
Innovations in infrastructure can be classified into two groups: grid management and
transmission and distribution grids.

Grid management: technologies oriented to operate more complex grids

Transmission and distribution grid: solutions that increase efficiency of the grids, mainly
by reducing losses
Table 4.8: Sample of relevant infrastructure developers
Besides the companies in Table 4.8, there are other organisms that are also developing and
researching in this field. Utilities are some of those as it is crucial to improve on their businesses.
For example, over 25 projects related to grids and grid management were developed by
Iberdrola during 2011-2013 [47]. CIGRE is another example. It is “an international non-profit
Association for promoting collaboration with experts all around the world by sharing knowledge
and joining forces to improve electric power systems of today and tomorrow” [48]. They organize
different events and meetings where they gather several experts in the matter. The last event in
Spain was held in Madrid on the 25th and 26th of November 2014. The main subjects of the
meeting were active management (i.e. new equipment, O&M and supply reliability) and future
networks (i.e. sustainability, smart grids and storage&electric vehicle).
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 76
These technologies will be adopted rapidly for two reasons. First, regulation, as in the case of
efficiency technologies, adapts as technology develops and goes making obligatory new
solutions. In Spain, by the end of 2016 all the meters in each access point have to be smart
meters. And second, the complexity brought by renewables to grids operation makes them
necessary in the future. The evolution of the grid is a necessary requirement in order to be able
to deal with the changes happening currently in the electric sector. Grid management has been
the field in which system operators have focused their efforts on.
The main disadvantage of HVDC grid is the high cost of the AC/DC and DC/AC converting
substations. Nowadays, the savings obtained by the reduction of losses only compensate the
expensive costs in long distances. As substations develop, they get more economical and the
distance gets shorter. It is likely that in the future HVDC grids will tend to substitute current
HVAC grids.
Chapter 4 | Energy innovation 77
Chapter 5
Changing electric sector
In the previous chapter the status of energy innovation has been presented. This chapter will
consist on analyzing how this innovation can change the electric sector. First, the discussion will
focus on which drivers can lead to a substantial change or prevent it from happening, disruptive
factors and barriers respectively. Finally, taking into account both, the innovative technologies
explained in the previous chapter and disruptive factors, three possible scenarios of the 2020
and 2030 generation mix will be presented.
5.1 Disruptive factors
Disruptive factors have been classified into two groups depending on the probability to occur
they have: on-going drivers and wildcards. On-going drivers are those factors that are very likely
to happen. They usually have an evolution over time and are currently going on. Their effect can
be somehow predicted and measures can be taken to adapt to the change. Wildcards however,
are those elements that are unlikely or less probable to happen. Moreover, they could happen in
a short period of time, in a long period or never happen; and are usually unpredictable, so it is
difficult to take preventive measures.
a) On-going drivers
The first to be considered is energy policy and governments. While renewable technologies
are not competitive by themselves, this is the driver that has the greater relevance and impact.
In a study developed by the World Energy Council in collaboration with A.T. Kearney [49], the
main driver of the change in all the analyzed countries was green energy policy. As a
consequence, the coming electric sector will be greatly shaped by the governments measures
and policies. In the last decades, since the Kyoto Protocol and the European 20-20-20 targets,
countries have gone towards the environmental sustainability in the trilemma. However, it seems
that some countries are trying to get back to energy equity (see the Spanish case in chapter 3 or
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 78
the British case in chapter 7). There are two ways in which governments can affect disruptively
the electric sector:

Direct support (i.e. subsidies): it is a driver with large relevance. Greater subsidies can
increase the learning and deployment pace of a technology. However, when talking about
the effect of government subsidies on renewables, it is important to take into account that
it is just a measure to give the initial impulse to a non-established technology, carry out
projects that without support would not be competitive and reduce costs in the meantime.
These subsidies will not last forever and there are some countries that start reducing
them due to an affordability issue (e.g. Spain, UK and Germany). So, it has to be
complemented by technology evolution and LCOE reduction. Wind and PV technologies
have been traditionally the more subsidized technologies. By the end of 2013, there were
already 117.3 GW [50] of wind capacity installed in Europe and 81.5 GW [51] of solar PV

Indirect support (i.e. regulatory framework): another way, apart from subsidies, of
supporting renewable energy is regulation. It especially affects in the case of distributed
generation. The tendency during the last years in more mature electric sectors has been
to move towards more liberalized frameworks. For example, a complete liberalization of
the commercialization activity would bring competitiveness and would leave place to new
entrants, presumably increasing the switching rates and reducing prices in the long term.
However, it is difficult that this liberalization happens in the short term in Spain. The
current government made the law 24/2013 setting the PVPC. So, it is difficult that they
derogate it and make a new one. The main possibilities of changing mainly depend on
the entrance of a new government
In the case of distributed generation, net metering would maximize the profitability of selfconsumption, while additional taxes to DG would stop its expansion. The Spanish
situation is currently closer to the last case after the draft RD of July 2013 that introduced
the possibility of the back-up toll
As technology and energy industry evolve, energy policies lose their relevance as disruptive
drivers. There are two relevant technology-related drivers that can be disruptive. The first one is
the LCOE reduction of renewable generation technologies. There are several technologies
that are becoming competitive rapidly and will make their space in the coming electric sector.
The main current barrier for renewable deployment is that they are expensive in comparison with
conventional technologies, but they are developing and quickly reducing LCOEs (see Chapter
4). Moreover, apart from being green ways of generation, renewables have a characteristic that
is likely to give them advantage over other technologies: the energy market´s Merit of Order
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 79
mechanism. In Spain, as long as market rules are not changed, renewables production will have
preference over conventional power plants. So, renewables load factor will be exclusively limited
by the resource availability, while conventional production will depend on renewable production.
Onshore wind, depending on site´s wind conditions, is already competitive with conventional
power plants (see Figure 4.10) and has been the main generation source after nuclear energy in
Spain for the last two years. Offshore wind is expected to reduce costs and have a wide
deployment (i.e. global offshore wind capacity of 39.9 GW in 2020 [52]). However, the
technology that is likely to be the most disruptive among all is solar PV. The expectations are
that PV panels costs will decrease following the learning curve shown in Figure 4.6. But, the Sun
Edison´s new manufacturing technique would mean a disruptive reduction on PV costs.
Additionally, due to its characteristics scalability and easy distributed deployment, solar
photovoltaic technology will contribute greatly on distributed generation expansion.
A new concept has been created with the expansion of distributed generation for selfconsumption, Prosumer. It refers to the consumer that at the same time is a producer. It will
become increasingly important as PV technology develops. Traditionally, investment decisions
have been taken on a “what is the best for the electric system?” basis. Distributed generation,
however, gives place to “what is the best for me?”, which often does not match with the best for
the system. This is translated in that competitiveness is not measured against conventional
generation technologies, but against electricity price. As electricity prices are constantly
increasing and the LCOE of PV is decreasing, there will be a moment in which it will be more
economical to produce your own energy than taking it from the grid (see Figure 5.1).
Figure 5.1: Electricity price and PV LCOE comparison [Eurostat and LCOE model]
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 80
The intersection between the LCOE and the electricity price will not happen at the same time all
over the world, it will highly depend on the location. PV competitiveness varies with the location
for two reasons: electricity price and the amount of solar irradiance. So, grid parity will happen
first in regions with high solar irradiance (lower LCOE) and more expensive electricity.
Figure 5.2: Solar irradiation (left) [Solar GIS] and example of LCOE for different regions (right)
Price of electricity depends mainly (if it is not subsidized as in the case of Canarias islands) on
the accessibility to the grid. This means that places that are not connected to the grid have more
expensive electricity. The reason is quite obvious, they have to be energy autonomous, having
their own ways of generating energy without benefiting of the scale economies that they may
have if they were connected to the grid. These locations are mainly islands and places far from
urban areas as deserts or rainforests.
So, it is logical to conclude that distributed generation with PV will start first in islands, and will
continue in places with high solar irradiance and it will progressively reach lower irradiance
locations.
As clean energy is reducing the LCOE and becoming a reality, conventional generation plants
are losing competitiveness. There are two factors that contribute to it: fossil fuels price
increase and CO2 penalties. Historical data of prices shows that the tendency is to increase (see
Figure 5.3). During the second semester of 2014, however, the Brent barrel´s price has
decreased more than a 50% due to a supply and demand imbalance. So, there is considerable
uncertainty in which direction oil price will go.
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 81
Figure 5.3: Fossil fuels price evolution [EIA and Eurostat]
Moreover, as seen in the previous chapter, CCS technology is still too costly and reduces power
plant´s output. But, in the meantime, this is the only way of keeping using fossil fuel technologies
while reducing CO2 emissions.
As seen in Figure 5.4, onshore wind is already competitive with fossil fuel technologies, PV will
become competitive with CCGT and hard coal by 2020 and offshore wind by 2030. As a
consequence, it seems likely that they would gain share in the generation mix. However, it is
important to remark that unless storage technologies deploy widely at utility scale, there will
always be the need of conventional generation plants to fill the gaps of power created by the
renewables intermittency and nuclear energy´s rigidity.
Figure 5.4: LCOE comparison for different generation technologies [“Levelized cost of electricity renewable energy
technologies”, Fraunhofer ISE – Nov. 2013]
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 82
Energy storage is the other technology development that will make the difference. Renewable
generation has always needed from other conventional technologies as back-up capacity due to
its intermittency. Storage systems are the method so that renewable technologies become
autonomous. Thus, an economic storage system will disruptively affect the electric sector and it
has become the R&D focus for many. These R&D efforts have resulted in many new
technologies and development, improvement and increasing competitiveness of the existing
ones. Tesla´s gigafactory (see chapter 4), for example, is likely to contribute to batteries cost
reductions by a 30% and become an important milestone in storage spread.
Energy storage can affect disruptively the electric sector in two main applications. First,
renewable integration at utility scale. It would reduce the dependency of fossil fuel as back-up
capacity and, theoretically, it would allow covering all the demand with renewable energy if the
energy storage capacity was large enough. Moreover, it would permit the energy generation not
to be exactly equal to the demand, this is, supply shift. Going to the extreme case, it would be
possible to have a system with just base load units, where energy is stored during periods of low
demand and released at peak moments. Energy storage used for this finality needs having high
power and energy capacities. So, pumped hydro storage, CAES, hydrogen or batteries could be
appropriate. According to Scott Van Pelt, director of engineering at Urban Green Energy,
“utilities are the biggest market right now because of their ability to install large amounts of
storage in just a few projects”.
The second application is self-consumption and distributed generation. It would allow prosumers
to consume at night energy generated during the day. As these systems are usually small and
located in houses, the properties required are mainly modularity, simplicity of usage and low
noise generation. Batteries are the most appropriated storage technology in this case.
Overall, disruption will come mainly leaded by batteries. A benchmark developed by the U.S.
Department of Energy has pointed the following targets for the battery industry: levelized cost of
storage under 20 ct$/kWh/cycle for the near-term (2014-2018) and under 10 ct$/kWh/cycle for
the long-term (2019-2023) [53]. It means that batteries would be already profitable for DG in
Spain by the near-term (as current power price is over 20 ct€/kWh) and profitable at utility scale
in the long-term. There is already a company claiming to offer batteries with a LCOE lower than
$0.12/kWh (i.e. EOS Energy Storage).
Finally, there are other drivers that, although their impact may be smaller, will also be important
in the reshaping of the coming electric sector. Electric vehicles´ competitiveness is one of
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 83
these. Although their deployment is relatively low nowadays (e.g. 50,000 rechargeable vehicles
sold in Europe in 2013, 0.4% of total amount [54]), the number of EV sold has doubled each
year since 2010 and there is people claiming that in 2030 the 100% of vehicles will be electric
[55]. The EV deployment pace will depend mainly in two aspects: EV cost reduction and
expansion of electric recharge stations. While the first of these aspects will be mainly given by
energy storage evolution, the second one will depend on political and economic interests.
Electric vehicles are likely to accentuate the already on-going tendency of electrification.
Smart grids development and optimization is another on-going driver. In this case, they are
not a disruptive factor, but a necessary factor for the system´s disruption. The electric sector is
changing from a monologue (i.e. the demand speaks and the supply listens and adapts the
generation) to a dialogue (i.e. there is communication from both sides optimizing the system).
Moreover, the entrance of renewable and distributed generation makes the system more
complex and difficult to manage. Smart grids are the technology that is going to allow this
concept evolution and make the management of the new complexity of grids possible. The
greatest R&D efforts of utilities and grid operators are made in this field of smart things (e.g.
grids, meters, cities).
The development of smart grids and the expansion of EVs will create a new way of energy
storage: electric vehicles as a storage method. Due to the mentioned dialogue between
demand and supply, the grid operator will be able to know which vehicles are charged and
connected to the grid in order to use their batteries as a source of energy. This is a cheap way of
increasing the storage capacity.
Finally, energy efficiency is having a fast development and, combined with the increasing
environmental consciousness, the trend is that their adoption will grow at very fast rates in the
future. One of the European targets for 2020 year is to improve efficiency by a 20% and the
World Energy Outlook 2013 predicts that energy intensity in residential buildings will decrease a
25% and global energy efficiency will improve in >30% by 2035.
b) Wildcards
These are some of the least probable drivers for disruption:

Unconventional oil/gas boom in Europe: as occurred in United States during the late
2000s, it would suppose a radical change of the energy system. Europe would decrease
their oil and gas imports reducing their dependency to other countries. It could even
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 84
happen that Europe became energy self-sufficient. It would likely mean a significant
reduction on natural gas prices as well as on oil prices. Nevertheless, unconventional oil
has several barriers in Europe. One of the most important is the restrictive regulation
which makes unconventional fossil fuels production much more expensive than in the
USA

Fusion becomes possible: electricity would be very cheap and it would change drastically
the electric sector. Generation would be done in a centralized way in a few nuclear fusion
power plants of high capacity. There are two kinds of possible fusions: “hot” fusion
(commonly known as nuclear fusion) and cold fusion. The ITER project and the
compact fusion of Lockheed Martin are the more developed cases of hot fusion. Cold
fusion is a nuclear fusion reaction that happens at room temperature and pressure. So, it
would not have the difficulties that hot fusion has, dealing with temperatures of millions of
degrees. However, it is thought to be impossible by the great majority of the scientific
community

European HVDC super-grid: why building a wind plant in Spain, with load factors
around 25%, instead of doing it in the north of Europe, with load factors >40%? Why
installing PV panels in Germany instead of doing it in the Sahara desert? The reason is
that the energy would have to be then transported across long distances and there would
be a lot of electrical losses. However, HVDC technology lets transmitting high quantity of
power over long distances with very few energy losses, but, constructing these lines
would be so expensive that a private entity would have difficulties to finance
There is already a project going on with this idea: Desertec project. The idea is
constructing huge plants of solar technology in North Africa and transmitting that power to
Europe in a HVDC grid. The project develops slowly due to lack of funding of the required
large amount of money

Nuclear disaster: Chernobyl and, specially, Fukushima have had a great impact on
society´s believing about nuclear energy. A good example of this are the two declarations
of Angela Merkel before and after what happened in Fukushima: “Seeing how many
power plants are being built worldwide, it would be a pity, if Germany would close down
nuclear power plants” (06/2009) and “The faster we can exit, the better. But it has to be
an exit with good judgment” (03/2011). So, if another nuclear disaster happened, many
nuclear plants would be questioned and shut down; leaving a big gap of base load units
that would have to be replaced quickly and as economically as possible
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 85

Other disasters (e.g. war, terrorist attack, epidemic diseases): it is difficult to know what
would happen if any of these disaster happened, but the electric sector would be likely to
change somehow
5.2 Barriers to the change
The regulatory barrier is one of the most important barriers to take into account. Favorable
regulation can launch renewable energy and contrary regulation can become the barrier that
prevents renewable technologies from expansion. Regulation varies across countries and may
change with new governments, so it can be a factor that freezes or slows down the expansion
pace for a while, but not permanently. Moreover, as world tends to a cleaner generation system,
regulation will tend not to be a barrier.
One of the clearest examples of regulation being a barrier is the Spanish case. The draft RD
announced in July 2013 introduced the concept of back-up toll. Technologies with good
characteristics for distributed generation that would have a rapid expansion without any support
from government, as solar PV, may be slowed down if this regulation goes on.
As the fourth factor in the energy trilemma, social acceptance can affect governments´
decisions and make them change regulation and reduce subsidies. It affects to all types of
technologies: conventional and renewables.

Fossil fuels: there are people that oppose this kind of technologies because they are
pollutant and are the origin of the global warming. People usually do not like having this
type of power plants nearby. In the case of unconventional oil/gas, there is an important
concern about pollution and the chemistry used for the drilling and production

Nuclear: people oppose nuclear energy because they think nuclear plants are dangerous
and a disaster can happen in anytime, as in Fukushima. Moreover, radioactive waste
takes too long to become safe and contaminates the environment. Usually, people do not
want to have a nuclear plant in their vicinity

Renewables: a very expanded idea is that renewable energy is expensive. In the last
years, there is an arising concern about economic affordability of renewable support (see
Spanish case in point 3.2 or British case in point 7.2). In order to fulfil European 20-20-20
objectives, governments have been heavily supporting renewable energy generation.
This has led to an increase on electricity price. So, there are people who question if this
is sustainable and who ask for subsidy reductions. As a consequence, some
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 86
governments are reducing their support to renewables (e.g. Spain, UK and Germany). In
addition, people have concerns about some technologies for the environmental impact
they may have. Some examples are stated below:
o
Wind energy: the construction of a wind park destroys the area where it is built
and they have a visual and acoustic impact. Moreover, birds are killed by the
blades of turbines
o
Hydroelectric: when a dam is built, the valley disappears under the water,
villages have to be evacuated, wild life disappears
o
Solar tower: thousands of birds are killed by abrasion annually
o
Ocean energy: marine life is perturbed and destroyed
There is another social barrier that may prevent disruption form happening: mindset barrier.
New technology means change and change brings distrust and disturbance of habits. So,
innovative and disruptive technologies usually have a progressive adoption that takes several
years (see Figure 5.5). It took more than 20 years before TV started being adopted and almost
40 years to have penetrations close to 100%. Recently appeared technologies (e.g. PC, internet
and mobile phone) have a faster adoption pace. Nevertheless, it took mobile phones more than
10 years to reach penetrations around 20-30%. This barrier has mainly effect on those
technologies that affect directly the consumer (e.g. home management products, distributed
generation or electric vehicles).
rd
Figure 5.5: Adoption of different technologies [33 Square]
The energy sector has been traditionally dominated by a few established players which are
making large profits. The disruption of the system means a threat for their source of revenues.
As a consequence, it is likely that these companies will become a barrier to the change by
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 87
lobbying and preventing new players from entering the market. A clear example is the case of
electric vehicles. EVs suppose a threat to oil companies as they are able to reduce drastically oil
consumption. So, they will make large efforts in order to try to slow down or freeze EV
expansion.
The last, but not least important, is the economic barrier. Two dimensions can be distinguished
in this point. First, as clean energy is an emerging industry, technologies are often more
expensive and have higher LCOE than conventional technologies. The second dimension is the
entrance barriers that the energy sector has: large capital investments are usually needed to
take part in the electric sector (e.g. anyone cannot build an offshore wind farm or own a
distribution grid). As a consequence, there are a few major players that have a big share of the
market, giving them some power to set the direction in which the system will go. Nevertheless,
technology development is enabling to overcome this barrier and there are lot of new companies
entering into the market, mainly in the field of distributed generation and energy efficiency.
5.3 2020 and 2030 scenarios of the electric sector
In this point, three scenarios are developed and analyzed. They are going to be a valuable tool
in chapter 6 in order to quantify the impact on utilities of each of the previously explained drivers.
The development and evolution of each scenario is based on different energy policies as they
are considered to be the main driver for disruption.
There is considerable uncertainty about which direction energy policies are going to take.
Recent events have polarized society. From one side, a segment of the population is concerned
about the greenhouse effect and human´s impact on earth. These people claim for greater
renewable support, even if it implies slightly more expensive electricity. From the other side, the
deep crisis in which Spain has been submerged has helped to realize the effect of renewable
support on electricity prices. Some people believe that the priority should be having economic
electricity and that renewable generation should not be supported by the government.
In Europe the situation is similar: there is a dilemma between environmental impact and
economic affordability. Some countries have started to reduce their support to renewable energy
or moving to more effective and efficient support mechanisms.
In this European and Spanish context, the following three scenarios are suggested:
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 88

Scenario 1 (base case): it is the central scenario based on the continuity of existing
energy policies. It assumes a tradeoff between environmental sustainability and energy
equity

Scenario 2 (economic affordability policies): regulator´s scope is focused in having a
sustainable system at the possible minimum price for the consumer. Energy equity gains
strength over environmental sustainability

Scenario 3 (green policies): it is the most disruptive scenario. Focus goes on
environmental sustainability while energy equity plays a secondary role
Figure 5.6: Energy trilemma balance by Scenario
The three scenarios will be based on a solid economic growth stage. After the economic crisis in
which Spain has been submerged, the economy seems to be recovering in 2014 and further
GDP increases are expected for the following years. Electricity demand declined considerably
during the crisis (i.e. from 265 TWh in 2008 to 243.5 TWh in 2014 [56]), so it is likely to grow as
the GDP does it. Historical data shows that electricity demand seems proportionally linked to
GDP growth [57]. So, economic growth of 3% CAGR is assumed in all the scenarios, resulting in
electricity demand increase of 30 TWh by 2020 and 70 TWh by 2030, without taking into account
efficiency measures.
Finally, each of the scenarios presented here are linked with one of the regulatory cases
developed in chapter 8. So, distributed generation policies and adoption figure for 2020 are
taken from that chapter. Scenario 1 is linked to the no regulation case, scenario 2 to the back-up
toll case and scenario 3 to the net-metering case.
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 89
5.3.1 Scenario 1: base case
Figure 5.7: Overview of Scenario 1
Spanish energy priority goes to a middle point between environmental sustainability and energy
equity in the energy trilemma. No changes are foreseen in the renewable energy support policy,
this is, renewable generation profitability remains linked to country´s 10 year´s interest. The draft
RD that introduced the back-up toll does not go on due to large opposition, but distributed
generation is neither supported.
Electrification has moderate absorption due to a moderate expansion of electric vehicles (2% by
2020 and 20% by 2030). They start being competitive to similar characteristic combustion
vehicles by the end of 2010s. However, their initial expansion is reduced due to the lack of
recharge infrastructure. In the 2020s, electric recharge stations start appearing as the share of
electric vehicles increases.
Efficiency continues improving, especially in residential buildings. However, this efficiency
improvement does not translate in a consumption decline because of electrification and
economic growth. The economic crisis of the beginning of the 2010s made electricity
consumption reduce and a new cycle of economic growth will make electricity demand increase
again and have a CAGR from 2014 to 2030 around 1%.
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 90
Renewable energy has a little expansion until 2020 (from 43% in 2014 to 45% in 2020) because
of the reduced profitability offered by the government subsidies and the higher LCOE than
conventional generation technologies (except from wind energy in certain locations with good
wind characteristics). By the end of the 2010 decade, wind energy starts being competitive with
conventional technologies in more locations and by the middle of the 2020 decade, solar energy
becomes competitive without subsidies at utility scale. Moreover, during this decade, energy
storage solutions start being profitable and make easier the renewable integration in the electric
system. As a consequence, renewable energy obtains shares of 51% by 2030.
Distributed generation has a moderate expansion and reaches the generation of almost 8 TWh
by 2020. Launched by affordable energy storage and solar PV LCOE reductions, distributed
generation increases its market share to 9% by 2030 and generates 24 TWh annually.
Nuclear moratorium continues and there is no new nuclear power plant development. So,
nuclear energy generation steadily declines over the 2020 decade and passes from generating a
22% of the electricity in 2014 to a 16% in 2030. Fossil fuel power plants initially increase slightly
their generation due to the demand increase. In the long run, however, their production is
conditioned by the renewable energy expansion and is used as back-up capacity.
The renewable energy expansion happening over the 2020 decade creates the need of
changing the current energy market mechanism. Technologies are separated into two groups
depending in their main characteristic: important for the capacity of supplying energy (e.g. most
renewable technologies and nuclear energy) and important for the capacity of assuring the
required power levels (e.g. coal plants, CCGT and hydroelectric energy). The first group is
remunerated according to the energy generated, while the second one depending on the
availability and power capacity.
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 91
5.3.2 Scenario 2: economic affordability policies
Figure 5.8: Overview of Scenario 2
In this scenario, the regulator opts for the energy equity in the energy trilemma. As special
regime support (i.e. renewable generation, cogeneration and waste) accounts for more than a
third of the grid access cost, it is suspended for new projects. Furthermore, the back-up toll is
established to guarantee the sustainability of grids.
Electrification has a reduced absorption. Expansion of electric vehicles is slowed down (0.5% by
2020 and 5% by 2030). They start being competitive to similar characteristic combustion
vehicles by 2020, but the lack of government support, reduced number of recharging stations
and strong lobby from O&G companies prevent them from giving the last step towards massive
expansion.
Energy efficiency continues improving, especially in residential buildings. However, this
efficiency adoption does not translate in a consumption decline due to strong economic growth.
Overall, electricity demand will increase again and have a CAGR from 2014 to 2030 under 0.5%
Renewable energy LCOE reduction is not as good as expected. This has its origin in fewer
renewable subsidies than expected at European and world level. So, the combination of no
support and low LCOE reduction results in almost null renewable expansion (i.e. 43% in 2020
and 2030). In addition, the back-up toll prevents distribution from expansion and it has almost
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 92
null absorption by 2020. In the 2020 decade, DG starts becoming profitable again and reaches 8
TWh generation by 2030.
Nuclear moratorium continues and there is no new nuclear power plant development. So,
nuclear energy generation steadily declines over the 2020 decade and passes from generating a
22% of the electricity in 2014 to a 16% in 2030.
Fossil fuel power plants increase their production to fulfill the gap left by the demand increase,
renewables´ weak situation and the nuclear moratorium. CCGT power plants generate ~28 TWh
by 2020 and ~37 TWh by 2030, while these figures are ~46 TWh and 50 TWh for coal plants.
The evolution of the generation mix allows the current energy market mechanism to continue
being sustainable.
5.3.3 Scenario 3: green policies
Figure 5.9: Overview of Scenario 3
Environmental sustainability wins the battle to energy equity in this scenario. Renewable energy
is heavily supported again and net metering is approved for distributed generation. Leaded by
social acceptance and influenced by the German case, a nuclear shutdown process starts: all
nuclear power plants should have to stop generation by 2030. In addition, electric vehicles are
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 93
supported in order to substitute oil consumption by electricity. Government supports EV with two
different methods: installing recharging stations and offering fiscal advantages.
As a consequence, electric vehicles have a fast adoption (i.e. 20% by 2020 and 60% by 2030).
Efficiency continues improving, especially in residential buildings. However, this efficiency
improvement does not translate in a consumption decline because of fast electrification and
economic growth. Electricity demand increases and has a CAGR from 2014 to 2030 of ~1.5%.
Renewable energy, promoted by subsidies, continues increasing its generation and reaches
shares of 55% by 2020. Energy storage´s LCOE evolves as expected and it is already
competitive at utility scale by the beginning of the 2020 decade. It is rapidly adopted and helps
solving renewable intermittency. It allows renewable energy to partially substitute the gap left by
the nuclear shutdown. Renewable generation reaches shares of 61% by 2030.
Distributed generation has a fast expansion promoted by net metering and reaches the
generation of 15 TWh by 2020. Launched by affordable energy storage and solar PV LCOE
reductions, distributed generation increases its market share to 14% by 2030 and generates 42
TWh annually.
The nuclear shutdown generates a base load energy gap. This gap is covered by renewable
energy with storage and coal plants. So, coal plants increase their generation from ~40 TWh in
2014 to near 50 TWh in 2030. CCGT power plants are used just for back-up capacity and their
production reduces to a 6% in 2020 and 5% by 2030.
The fast renewable energy expansion makes the current energy market mechanism
unsustainable. The existing problem with profitability of CCGT plants worsens and creates the
need of changing the current energy market mechanism. Technologies are separated into two
groups depending in their main characteristic: important for their capacity of supplying energy
(e.g. most renewable technologies and coal plants) and important for their capacity of assuring
the required power levels (e.g. CCGT and hydroelectric energy). The first group is remunerated
according to the energy generated, while the second one depending on the availability and
power capacity.
Chapter 5 | Changing electric sector 94
Chapter 6
Potential impact on utility companies
In the previous chapter, the main disruptive factors have been shown. These drivers are
originating some trends that are likely to change the Spanish electric system. As previously
mentioned, the main driver for disruption lays in energy policies and it is the main difference
between scenarios. Table 6.1 resumes the trends originated by the on-going drivers and their
effect on the different scenarios.
Table 6.1: Overview of disruptive factors and consequences
Before discussing the impact it is necessary to better understand the sources of revenue and
profitability of the different business for utilities. The financial statements of two sample utilities
have been analyzed (Iberdrola Spain and Enel Group). The main revenue of the Spanish utility
is generated in conventional generation and commercialization businesses, while profitability
comes greatly from electricity distribution. The 82% of the revenue comes from conventional
generation and commercialization, 12% distribution networks and 7% renewables generation.
The business that generates the largest EBITDA is distribution (41%), followed by conventional
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 95
generation and commercialization (39%) and finally renewable generation (20%). It is important
to realize that although distribution has the higher EBITDA/Revenue ratio, it requires of large
investments, having large amortization expenses and lower Benefit/Revenue ratio. These
numbers are similar in the case of Enel (see Figure 6.1).
Figure 6.1: Revenues and EBITDA for Iberdrola Spain 2013 (left) and Enel Group Italy 2013 (right) [Annual reports]
These revenue and profits are being threatenend by the the different trends that are changing
the electric sector. There are many challenges and some opportunities arising. Utilities will need
to face the challenges and adapt to the new situation in order to maintain their profit level. In the
meantime, they should leverage some of the opportunities. The following table shows the
different challenges and opportunities on each incumbent utility business segment.
Table 6.2: Potential impact on incumbent utility business
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 96
a) Generation

Wholesale price could reduce up to a 10% by 2020 in Scenario 3
There are two factors that could reduce the wholesale price. The first one is a decrease on the
demand. From one side, distributed generation and efficiency measures directly reduce the
amount of electricity needed, and storage systems contribute to a deeper reduction of the
demand as they are likely to reduce DG systems dependency to the grid. From the other side,
electrification will bring an increase on electricity needs. Overall, the majority of predictions point
that Spanish electricity demand is likely to increase (i.e. from 248 TWh in 2013 to 258 TWh in
2017 [58]).
The second factor is the irruption of low opportunity cost technologies such as renewable
energy. As the markets follow a Merit of Order mechanism, low opportunity cost plants displace
more expensive ones and the demand is fulfilled with more economic technologies. Its impact on
the wholesale price is easily noticeable when there are abundant precipitations or strong winds
(e.g. wholesale price was under 20 €/MWh for several days in March/April 2013 due to good
renewable resources). However, it is difficult to measure the impact of renewable energy in the
long run. Some theoretical studies state that each 10% increase of the amount supplied by
renewables yields a decrease in the average wholesale price of 6.5 MWh/€ [59]. Moreover,
Spanish average wholesale price in the free market has decreased an 8% from 2011 to 2014
while the demand increased a 6% and renewable generation grew in 6 p.p.
Figure 6.2: Free market wholesale price and demand evolution [OMIE]
In Scenario 1 and Scenario 2, wholesale price would slightly increase (~1-2%) by 2020 leaded
by a demand growth and a moderate renewable expansion. This trend would keep until 2030,
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 97
when prices would have increased 1% and 5% respectively. In Scenario 3, however, renewable
generation share passes from 43% in 2014 to 55% in 2020 and 61% in 2030. It would mean a
price decrease of ~10% (~50 €/MWh) in 2020 and 20% (~45 €/MWh) in 2030.
Table 6.3: Wholesale price predictions by scenario

Merit of Order gradually unsuitable energy market mechanism
As explained in chapter 3, energy markets are ruled by a Merit of Order mechanism based in the
opportunity cost. This mechanism was designed so that base load units (usually rigid and
reliable technologies with low operating costs) were sold first. Thus, the majority of the demand
would be covered by base load units and the resting by intermediate or peak units. Renewable
energy was a minority (less than 2% excluding hydroelectric) when the Merit of Order
mechanism was established in 1997. Nowadays, renewable energy is the main generation
source with over the 26% of the electricity generation in 2014 and all the evidences (see
Disruptive factors in chapter 5) point that RES will keep increasing generation capacity in the
future. And, if the effect of distributed generation (i.e. potential to cover up to 11.4 GW of the
power demand during midday, see chapter 8) is additionally taken into account, the thermal gap1
is likely to shrink considerably, especially during midday hours.
The reduction of the thermal gap supposes a serious threat for the system´s sustainability. One
consequence is that power plants that traditionally were considered intermediate units, such as
combined cycles, have considerably lower load factors than predicted when they were build.
This is a fact already happening in Spain. The annual average load factor of combined cycles in
2008 was over 50% and has reduced to 11.4% in the first ten months of 2014 [60]. As a result,
CCGT power plants are not profitable anymore and the great majority of combined cycle
operators want to close them: they are suggesting a permanent massive shutdown of combined
cycles. However, the system needs these flexible technologies in order to guarantee the power
supply, as renewable generation technologies are a source of energy but do not guarantee the
1
Difference between power demand and power generated by RES, covered by conventional technologies
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 98
required power capacity in every moment. This problem will continue worsening as renewables
continue increasing their share.
Under the threat of a massive CCGT plant shutdown, the government has reacted by proposing
a hibernation plan [61]. It consists on the temporary shutdown of some combined cycles, but not
decommissioning it. The proposed solution by combined cycle operators is a change of the
remuneration method. This mechanism pays CCGT operators for the power availability instead
of for the energy generated, as they are important for their power capacity and not for the
amount of energy generated. However, this would probably mean an increase on the system
costs, having two main alternatives for paying them: increasing electricity price to consumers or
reducing revenue to other technologies.
Another grave result is the possibility of a nuclear shutdown. If renewable energy´s deployment
endures and the thermal gap keeps diminishing, the point in which nuclear power plants have to
be shutdown could be reached. If renewable energy had a penetration large enough, it might
occur that the space left for nuclear energy was smaller than the whole nuclear capacity. As
nuclear power plants are very rigid and are unable to adapt their output power to renewable
generation´s pattern, the exceeding nuclear capacity would need to close.
In consequence, the current Merit of Order mechanism is becoming gradually unsuitable and
unsustainable as renewable generation increases. There will be an increasing need of
substituting it for an appropriate method that guarantees the sustainability of the electric system.

CCGT plants may reduce their load factor to 8.16% and their revenues in 300 million €
by 2020
As explained in the previous point, RES deployment has an impact on CCGT power plants. In
Scenario 3, the electricity generated by combined cycles would decrease to the 6% of the total
electricity consumption, resulting in a load factor of 8.16%1. It would mean a reduction of 6 TWh
in their production and, assuming a wholesale price of 50 €/MWh, revenues would reduce
almost in 300 million €.

Economic growth originated by the end of the crisis will contribute to increase revenues
in 1,500-1,650 million € by 2020
1
Assuming that CCGT capacity does not change from actual figures
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 99
During the development of scenarios in chapter 5, one assumption has been that Spain would
have solid economic growth from 2014 to 2030 and it electricity demand increases. The
assumption has been of 30 TWh by 2020. Assuming wholesale prices in Table 6.3, revenues
would increase around 1,500-1,650 million € by 2020.

Efficiency measures could reduce in 900-1,400 million € the revenues from generation
by 2020
Although electricity demand is likely to increase in all the scenarios, this raise is going to be
slowed down by efficiency measures. An annual 1% of efficiency improvement would imply a
reduction of the potential electricity demand in the range of 16-17 TWh by 2020. Assuming
wholesale prices in Table 6.3, the amount of revenues that utilities would stop to earn is around
900 million €. These figures could increase up to 25 TWh and 1,400 million € if efficiency
improved annually a 1.5%.
IEA´s prediction in the World Energy Outlook 2013 that residential buildings would reduce
electricity consumption a 25% by 2030 would imply an annual reduction of ~18 TWh1, or 900
million €.

Distributed generation would additionally reduce revenues up to 750 million € by 2020
Distributed generation has the potential to generate from almost 8 TWh (Scenario 2) to 15 TWh
(Scenario 3) by 2020. Each kWh generated by DG means one kWh less consumed from the
grid. Assuming wholesale prices in Table 6.3, this would mean a revenue reduction of 440-750
million € by 2020. These figures would increase to 1,300-1,900 million € in 2030.

Revenues could potentially increase in 300 million € by 2020 if EVs were leveraged
In a society that tends to reduce the energy used to do things, electrification is the main lever to
increase electricity consumption. Electric vehicles have the greatest potential for this purpose.
An EV consumes between 12 and 20 kWh/100km. Assuming 50 km/day and a consumption of
15 kWh/100km, one million electric vehicles would consume 2.7 TWh in one year. Revenues
generated by EV consumption would be almost 300 million € greater in Scenario 3 than in
Scenario 2 by 2020 and up to 1,450 million € by 2030 (see Table 6.4).
1
Annual consumption for the totality of consumers <10 kW = ~70 TWh
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 100
Table 6.4: Adoption and impact of electric vehicles by scenario

The end of vertically integrated utilities
While the majority of revenue comes from conventional generation and commercialization
(82%), the larger amount of EBITDA (61%) is due to distribution and renewable generation.
Moreover, the expansion of renewable technologies reduces the utilization factor of conventional
generation technologies. So, electric utilities have to deal with a difficult challenge: moving
towards renewable energy while keeping the profitability of conventional technologies. It is a
difficult step and seems impossible to fulfill both objectives at the same time. At least, this is
what E.ON has thought; they have decided to separate their activities into two different and
independent companies [62]: one responsible for renewables and grids areas, and the other for
conventional generation technologies. Other utilities could follow E.ON´s steps and separate the
more and less profitable businesses into two different companies.
b) Transmission and distribution

Distributed generation may increase a 2.5% electricity price per kWh respectively
Electric system costs can be divided into two groups: energy costs and grid access costs (e.g.
T&D grids investment and operation, especial regime support, annual deficit payments). This
last group is independent to the energy consumed. Incomes to cover grid access costs have two
different origins (see Figure 6.3). First, every person or company connected to the grid has to
pay a toll for the contracted capacity, independently of the energy consumed. The second
source is the variable term. From the price of each kWh consumed, a fraction goes to pay the
system´s fixed costs. This income structures originates that, if the energy consumed decreases,
the system´s incomes will decline while expenses do not change. Thus, any reduction of the
consumed electricity supposes a threat for the electric system. In order to compensate the
imbalance between incomes and costs, grid access tolls would have to be increased, either the
fixed or the variable term. Let´s put numbers to this problem.
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 101
Figure 6.3: Structure of system costs and grid access tariff [“Análisis del autoconsumo en el Mercado del sector
eléctrico español”, Iberdrola – May 2012]
In the case of distributed generation, the potential reduction is up to 15 TWh by 2020 in Scenario
3. The 34% of the energy is consumed by residential consumers and small companies (2.x
tariffs), while big consumers (6.x tariffs) account for the 45% of the consumed energy. The 74%
of the energy dependent incomes come from small consumers, while a 12% comes from big
consumers (see Figure 6.4). A consumption reduction 15 TWh would suppose a revenue
reduction of the energy term incomes of 288 million € over the total 4,382 million €1. If the
measure for compensating this imbalance was increasing the energy term, this toll would have
to increase a 7% its collected incomes. In the PVPC tariff, for example, it would mean a 2.5%
increase on the price per kWh2.
1
Assuming that the consumption reduction occurs uniformly over all tariffs
2
65% of the incomes per kWh are directed to cover generation expenses and 35% to grid access costs
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 102
Figure 6.4: Energy consumption and grid access incomes by tariffs for distribution companies with > 100,000
consumers [“Informe sobre la liquidación provisional 7/2014 del sector eléctrico”, CNMC]
In order not to increase the electricity bill, the government brought up a possible solution in the
draft RD of July 2013 (i.e. back-up toll). It is based on that, as self-consumption units keep
connected to the grid and have the need of it, they should also contribute to its maintenance. It
seems to be a measure to worsen the economics of DG and stop its expansion, instead of being
a measure to ensure grid maintenance. However, technology development and increasing
competitiveness would make self-consumption profitable again in a short/medium period of time.
Moreover, this hypothetic measure would foster the DG with storage. As units not connected to
the grid would not have to pay for back-up toll, the economics of self-consumption with storage
would improve significantly against non-storage solutions. It would suppose even a worse
scenario than the previous one.
Another possible solution could be that grid costs were assumed by the government and
became another expense in the general administration budget. It seems to be a reasonable
solution if it is taken into account that transmission and distribution grids are a national interest
infrastructure, as they guarantee access to energy for every Spanish citizen.
In any case, the answer to this challenge is not trivial and regulators will need to find a
satisfactory solution that guarantees system´s sustainability.

Distributed generation with storage would reduce in 63.3 million € grid access
revenue per each gigawatt disconnected from the grid
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 103
Energy storage exacerbates the reduction of grid access incomes due to distributed generation.
Storage allows the complete independence from the grid, not having to pay for the capacity term
of the grid access toll. Just the impact of 2.0A consumers is analyzed as the effect of others
tariffs is smaller (2.X tariffs proportionally pay more grid access tolls than other tariffs, see Figure
6.4). The impact of reducing 1 GW capacity for the tariff 2.0A is shown in Table 6.5.
Table 6.5: Impact calculation of DG with storage

Extra grid capacity needed to deal with electrification is viable in the required time
frame
The electricity demand increase caused by electrification can potentially leave the grid unable to
supply the required power. However, as electrification is likely to be leaded by electric vehicles
expansion and these vehicles will probably be recharged at night (while they are not being
used), in a first view, it seems that it would not be a critical challenge. Let´s put some numbers.
In the green policies scenario, electricity consumption due to EV deployment would increase in
36 TWh by 2030. Assuming all EVs are charged every day during the same time frame of eight
hours, it would mean an extra power demand of 12.4 GW. Additionally, if it is assumed that this
time frame coincides with the peak demand period, the maximum power demand would be 51
GW (peak power demand of 38.9 GW in 2014 [63]). The peak power demand in 2007 was 45.45
GW [64]. So, grids would have to be able to supply 6 GW of power more in 2030 than in 2007,
which seems reasonable and viable in a 23 years gap.
c) Commercialization

Liberalization could allow increasing margins up to +5 p.p. while improving satisfaction
indexes
The complete liberalization of the commercialization could bring potential benefits for both,
consumers and utility companies. From one side, it would allow utilities to offer value added
services in the electricity contract. They could offer efficiency and home management services
or a dual tariff of gas and electricity, potentially reducing the price of the combination. Free
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 104
commercialization ends generating higher satisfaction in countries with a complete liberalized
market (see Figure 6.5).
1
Figure 6.5 : Potential reduction of dual tariffs (left) [Comparador de ofertas de energía CNMC] and satisfaction
indexes (right) [European Commission]
Additionally, it allows utilities to increase their commercialization margins. With the current PVPC
tariff, the commercialization income is 4 €/kW/year, resulting on a 3% commercialization margin
for the average PVPC consumer2. In Spain, the average commercialization margin for liberalized
tariffs is 7% and it is an 8% in the UK (see Figure 6.6). So, the margin could potentially increase
to a 7-8% (9-11 €/kW/year). These new margins would readjust the cost and income
disequilibrium that generates the tariff deficit.
Figure 6.6: Commercialization margins for different countries [CNMC, Ofgem, Observatoire de l´industrie Electrique]
1
Contracted power = 3.3 kW, electricity consumption = 3,000 kWh and gas consumption = 7,500 kWh
2
Contracted power = 3.9 kW and electricity consumption = 2,123 kWh
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 105

Distributed generation opens the door to enter non-traditional regions
Entering non-traditional regions is a complicated task as commercializing margins are usually
low and there is no big difference between offers of different commercializers. Distributed
generation creates the opportunity to enter these regions, especially those with better solar
resources such as Andalucía or Extremadura. A simplified example is shown next 1.
Based on A.T. Kearney´s photovoltaic LCOE model, the LCOE for PV panels in the south of
Spain would be ~10 cent€/kWh by 2020. Assuming an annual growth of 2% on the PVPC
electricity price2, the price for residential consumers would be around 14 cent€/kWh, almost 40%
higher. Utilities could offer discounts of 10-15%3 on electricity (around 12-12.5 cent€/kWh) if the
consumer allowed the installation of a PV system in his rooftop.
Additionally, it gives utilities the opportunity to control the deployment pace of distributed
generation. As LCOE reduces and electricity price increases, distributed generation with PV is a
reality that will come sooner or later and it will allow new players to enter to the electric sector.
Being the one who offers DG can make entrance more difficult for those new players.

Electrification has to be leveraged
Apart from increasing the consumed energy, electrification can be used as a marketing tool by
commercializers and make easier the entrance to non-traditional regions. So, if leveraged
correctly, electrification would be greatly beneficial for utilities. The followings are some
examples of how utilities could launch electrification and at the same time use it as a
commercialization tool:

An especial tariff for those consumer that own an electric vehicle and recharge it at home

Funding a certain percentage of EV price if a term contract of electricity supply is signed
for some years

Lobbying or reaching agreements with local governments in order to install EV chargers
in streets

A cooperation agreement with an EV manufacturer
1
Numbers are not exhaustive, just explanatory example
2
12.41 cent€/kWh in 2014 for 2.0A tariff
3
Assuming half of the energy produced with PV and the rest taken from the grid
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 106
To conclude, Table 6.6 summarizes and groups the different impacts. Overall, the future does
not seem easy for utilities. They are threatened to lose some of their current revenues. This
impact will mainly depend on two factors. First, electricity demand. It is uncertain which will be
the evolution of the demand. From one side, it seems reasonable to suppose it will grow after
the great depression it has suffered during the last economic crisis. Moreover, electrification will
gain power as electric vehicles become competitive. Efficiency measures, however, are a
relevant threat that could cause a demand decline. For example, if the annual efficiency
improvement was 1%, utilities would be likely to increase revenues in Scenario 1 and 2. But, if
the improvement was of 1.5%, there would be high risk of revenue decrease. The second factor
is distributed generation. It would reduce electricity demand from the grid even if overall
electricity consumption might increase. It could reduce revenues in up to 750 million € by 2020
and almost in 2,000 million € by 2030 in Scenario 3.
In addition, conventional generation technologies, especially CCGT, are highly threatened by
renewable generation expansion. The great majority of CCGT power plants are already
unprofitable and the situation seems to get worse for them.
Finally, the electric system is in danger of unsustainability. The regulator has a complex task to
carry: the current energy market mechanism has to be adapted to the new paradigm of the
electric sector and the problem of the grid access income reduction has to be resolved.
Table 6.6: Summary of the different impacts on utilities
Chapter 6 | Potential impact on utility companies 107
Chapter 7
Practical case 1: Can we afford
renewable energy? Learnings from UK
wind offshore
Renewable energy expansion is a trend that is going on in many mature electric systems. Green
policies taken by different European countries are being reflected in power price increases and
some are beginning to rethink the support mechanism in order to reduce its impact on the final
consumer. This is the case of the UK, which is currently going through a transformation phase of
its energy policy. It is a representative example of what could happen in other European
countries. This chapter will explain this process with special focus on the offshore wind industry.
It is a quite immature and new technology that is evolving rapidly and it is thought to be one of
the main sources of energy in the North Europe countries by 2030. Additionally, UK is the
leading country in this industry, having the larger installed capacity in the actuality and the
prediction to be the country with greater capacity of offshore wind by 2020 [65].
7.1 UK´s renewable situation
7.1.1 2020 Objectives
As all European countries, the UK made the commitment to fulfill the European 20/20/20 targets
in 2020. The objectives for the UK are the followings:
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 108
2020 targets
2005 levels
Emissions reduction targets (compared to 2005 levels)
-16%
-
Renewable energy (in % of gross final energy consumption)
15%
1.4%
Energy efficiency (primary energy consumption expressed in Mtoe)
177.6
240.4
Table 7.1: European 20/20/20 targets for UK [European Commission website]
7.1.2 Affordability issue: renewable support called into question
Among the trilemma of competing energy needs (see Figure 3.10), environmental sustainability
has dominated during the last years in UK, guided by the 2020 European targets. This has led to
an increase on energy prices. Electricity prices have increased with a CAGR of 5% since 1978
and gas prices with a CAGR of 6%, as it is seen in Figure 7.1.
Figure 7.1: Historic evolution of domestic gas and electricity price [“Energy Affordability: The Rising Tide on UK
Shores”, A.T. Kearney - 2014]
Moreover, predictions are that they will continue increasing with a CAGR of 6% and 4%
respectively.
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 109
Figure 7.2: Domestic gas and electricity price projections [“Energy Affordability: The Rising Tide on UK Shores”,
A.T. Kearney - 2014]
It is difficult to say which the reasons of this price increase are or which the effect of renewable
support on this change has been. However, it seems that green policies have had and will have
the greatest effect in price rises. Costs derived by UK green policy are expected to increase
11.4% annually and EU policy costs by 20%, rising on £210 the average dual fuel bill between
2013 and 2024.
Figure 7.3: Average consumer dual fuel bill projections price [“Energy Affordability: The Rising Tide on UK Shores”,
A.T. Kearney - 2014]
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 110
There are people starting to point out the affordability of renewables subsidies and it has already
become a political issue: the Conservatives are moving some green costs into the general
taxation system, Labour party has promised to freeze energy prices and everyone blames the
energy companies for profiteering. Affordability is gaining again great relevance on UK´s
trilemma.
7.1.3 Malfunctioning subsidy framework
From one side, the affordability issue has been caused by an ineffective renewable support
mechanism. The Renewables Obligation (RO) is the main support mechanism for renewable
technologies in the UK. It came into force in 2002. The mechanism works as follows:

Electricity suppliers in UK have the obligation to source an increasing proportion of the
electricity they supply from renewable resources. This proportion is set annually by
regulators. In order to demonstrate they have met with this obligation, suppliers have to
present a sufficient number of Renewable Obligation Certificates (ROCs)

ROCs are green certificates issued to operators of renewable generating stations for the
renewable electricity they generate. They can be traded by operators to other parties

If suppliers do not present a sufficient number of ROCs to meet their obligation, they
must pay an equivalent amount into a buy-out fund. The administration cost of the
scheme is recovered from the fund and the rest is distributed back to supplier in
proportion to the number of ROCs they produced in respect of their individual obligation
In a simpler way, each renewable operator receives a number of ROCs for each MWh it
generates. This number depends on the renewable technology (see Table 7.2). Then, electricity
suppliers buy these certificates to fulfill the required amount they are obligated. This means that
the price, in which each ROC is sold by operators to suppliers, depends on the required amount
of ROCs by supplier and the quantity of ROCs produced. So, the price is not going to be fixed,
but fluctuates with the market. However, it is usually around the buy-out price fixed by the
regulator (see Table 7.3).
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 111
Table 7.2: Received RO Certificates for a sample of technologies [DECC]
Table 7.3: Historic buy out price for RO certificates [Ofgem]
Focusing on the revenues received by renewable plant operators, they would result in the
following:
LEC (Levy Exemption Certificates) are some certificates that non-domestic end users of energy
can purchase in order not to pay a Climate Change Levy of £4.3 per MWh. It is a similar system
to RO but with non-domestic end users of energy. It is a small amount compared to the rest of
the revenues, thus, it will not be analyzed in greater depth.
For instance, an offshore wind operator would have earned in 2013 per MWh generated:

Wholesale price: £60-70/MWh (April)

Number of ROCs per MWh: 2

ROC price: £42.02

LEC: ~£4/MWh
Total revenues ≈ £150-160/MWh
ROCs are given to all those who apply and meet the required specifications; and the support has
a duration of 20 years. Hence, RO mechanism has mainly three advantages for operators: there
is not a competitive process to obtain ROCs, it is a 20 year support and revenues are usually
high.
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 112
The main drawback from the renewable operator point of view is that revenues fluctuate. On one
side, the revenues depend on the wholesale market. On the other side, ROCs price can
fluctuate even if they usually move around the buy-out price. This means that there is no
certainty of which the exact revenues are going to be, increasing the risk of projects and, in the
meantime, the interest demanded by financial institutions.
However, the real disadvantages are suffered by the end consumer of electricity. ROC costs are
added by suppliers to final power prices, increasing them as seen in the previous point.
Moreover, as it is not a competitive process, renewable power plant developers do not make
efforts to reduce cost and improve efficiency as they would do if they were competing to each
other for the subsidy. It results in low improvements in LCOE. This means that people are
supporting renewables in order to pollute less and have an affordable renewable energy in the
future, and the result is that their bills continue increasing but renewable generation does not
reduce costs, creating the affordability problem.
7.1.4 Industry failing to deliver
In the meantime, the offshore wind industry has not developed as it was thought. Costs have not
decreased as low as expected, leading to higher actual LCOE figures than predicted. Fraunhofer
ISE predicted that the LCOE in 2015 would be in the range of £86-140/MWh [66]. The actual
LCOE can be assumed to be in the range of the price per MWh that the UK government is ready
to pay in the new support mechanism, around £130-140/MWh.
Figure 7.4: Predicted and actual offshore wind LCOE comparison
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 113
7.2 New regulatory framework
The two solutions to the affordability problem taken by the UK government are, from one side,
reducing renewable capacity targets, and from the other side, changing the renewable support
mechanism. In the UK renewable energy roadmap of 2011 [67], the prediction was of 18 GW for
offshore wind by 2020. It was reduced to 16 GW in the 2013 edition [68] and nowadays, this
number has gone to 10 GW [69].
In January 2013, the UK government launched the Electricity Market Reform (ERM) [70]. It is a
government policy to incentivize in secure, low-carbon electricity, improve the security of Great
Britain´s electricity supply, and improve affordability for costumers. ERM introduced two main
mechanisms:

A Capacity Market (CM), which will help ensure security of electricity supply at the least
cost to the consumer

Contracts for Difference (CfD), which will provide long-term revenue stabilization for new
low carbon initiatives
The focus in this work will be in the CfD as it is the new renewable support mechanism that will
occupy the place of Renewable Obligations.
7.2.1 Transition from Renewable Obligation Certificates (ROC) to Contract
for Difference (CfD)
Nowadays, RO and CfD mechanism are living together during the transition from one to the
other. ROCs will come to an end in March 2017. Projects developed before this date can still
apply for them. The first CfD allocation round has taken place from October 2014 to February
2015.
The new mechanism guarantees a fixed price per MWh for 15 years whatever the wholesale
price is; the difference between the awarded price and the wholesale price is subsidized. For
example, if a renewable power plant operator receives the CfD at £130/MWh, the government
guarantees that for 15 years this plant will earn that amount for each MWh generated. If one day
the wholesale price is £50, the subsidy will pay for the difference, £80; and if the next day it is
£70, the subsidy will decrease to £60. This implies a good advantage for power plant operators.
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 114
As incomes are guaranteed, it reduces the risk of projects, having easier bankability and lower
finance costs.
Another change introduced by CfD mechanism is the way it is granted. ROCs were awarded to
all those projects of renewable energy that met with some requirements. CfD, however, is given
by a competitive process. One allocation round will be held each year, being the first one in
October 2014. Each allocation round works as follows:

The government fixes a maximum budget. The budget can be divided into different pots.
Renewable technologies will be grouped in one of those pots depending on their maturity.
Each pot has its own competitive process, being the regulation equal but autonomous
between them. This is done because less mature technologies (e.g. offshore wind) could
not compete in price with more mature technologies (e.g. onshore wind)

The government fixes the Administrative Strike Price (ASP). It is the maximum price per
MWh that each technology could aim for (£/MWh)

The candidates present their projects: technology, size, commissioning date, etc.

The required budget for giving the CfD to all the projects is calculated. If it does not
exceed the announced budget, all of them are given the CfD at the ASP. If it does, the
auction begins
In order to calculate the impact that a project of certain technology and size has on the budget,
the following formula is used:
Where the reference price is the estimated average wholesale price on the year the project is
expected to be commissioned and it is given by the regulator. Load factor is the ratio between
the predicted average generated energy over the possible maximum energy. It depends on the
conditions of each location, but the regulator fixes it so that projects are comparable between
them. Capacity is the power installed in MW. TLM (Transmission Loss Multiplayer) is a factor
included not to take into account losses during the transmission of the power from the
generation location to the grid.
The main principles of the auction are the followings:
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 115

Each candidate presents a bid with a strike price (limited by the ASP), the size of its
project and the commissioning year

Bids are ordered from the lowest strike price to the largest

First bid is considered. Its impact in the budget is calculated with the previous formula

If it fits in the budget, it is awarded a CfD contract. And next bid is considered

If a bid does not fit in the budget, the commissioning year of that bid is closed. All others
bids with the same commissioning year are discarded

When all years are closed or there are no more bids, the auction ends
Being a competitive process means that candidates will try to reduce its costs to the minimum
and become as competitive as possible, reducing the incomes for each MWh and the cost for
consumers. With the RO mechanism, an offshore wind could earn up to £150-160 for each MWh
generated. In the first CfD allocation round, the ASP was £140/MWh (see Table 7.6) and the
winner offshore projects have obtained a CfD price in the range of £114-120/MWh.
7.2.2 First CfD allocation round overview
It took place during Q4 2014. These are the key initial dates for this round (see Figure 7.5): until
October 30 submission of the candidates; in November 13, notice if there is need of auction or
not; in case of auction, bids have to be presented before December 9; and finally, winners are
known in January 2015.
Figure 7.5: Initially proposed key dates on CfD process [DECC]
Initial situation
In June 2014, there are 10 potential offshore wind candidates to apply for a CfD contract. The
main characteristics of each of them are showed in Table 7.4. Four of these candidates can
potentially also apply for ROCs due to their early commissioning date (i.e. Rampion, Race Bank,
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 116
Neart na Gaiothe and Galloper). Projects larger than 300 MW have to submit a Supply Chain
Plan (SCP) in September. This SCP has to show mainly three things: project is feasible and has
low risks, technology used is innovative and it will bring several local benefits. The SCP will be
then examined and marked. In order to be eligible in this allocation round, the SCP has to be
successful.
Table 7.4: Main characteristics of projects initially competing for a CfD [4coffshore]
The budget has not been announced yet, but it is thought to be big enough to allocate around 2
GW of offshore wind.
Process
The 24th of July, the government publishes a draft budget notice, showing a first draft of the
ASPs, pots and budget. Three pots are defined, but just two of them have a budget.

Pot 1 (established technologies): Onshore wind (>5MW), Solar PV (>5mW), Energy from
Waste with CHP, Hydro (>5mW and <50MW), Landfill Gas and Sewage Gas

Pot 2 (less established technologies): Offshore Wind, Wave, Tidal Stream, Advanced
Conversion Technologies, Anaerobic Digestion, Dedicated biomass with CHP and
Geothermal, Scottish island onshore wind

Pot 3: biomass conversion
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 117
1
Table 7.5: Budget distribution between pots [DECC]
Table 7.6: Administrative Strike Price by Commissioning date and technology [DECC]
A budget of £155m in the Pot 2 means that the maximum capacity of offshore wind that can
obtain a CfD contract (at the ASP and supposing being the only allocated technology) is less
than 550 MW. It means a big reduction in comparison to the 2 GW previously thought. It is also
announced that a minimum of 10 MW of Wave and Tidal technologies have to be allocated,
leaving space for ~500 MW of offshore wind. Moreover, Scottish islands onshore wind is likely to
be in the same pot. It is a project of 370 MW in a location of very good wind conditions, making it
highly competitive and potentially leaving a very low budget for offshore wind. This means that,
1
The Budget of £155m is the total Budget for all the years, not for each individual year, e.g., a project of
£100m in year 2016/17 takes that amount from all the years, not only from 2016/17
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 118
in the best scenario, an only offshore project will be successful and that there is no space for the
biggest ones.
In September, Navitus Bay, Triton Knoll, Race Bank and Seagreen Alpha do not deliver the
SCP, going out of the competition for the CfD.
The 2nd of October, DECC makes the final budget announcement with two main changes:
Scottish islands onshore wind is not in Pot 2 and the budget is changed, increasing the amount
of Pot 1 to £65m and to £235m in Pot 2. This announcement has two positive points: first, as
Scottish island onshore wind is left out Pot 2, competition is reduced, potentially increasing the
proportion of Pot 2 budget going for offshore wind; and the budget increase means that there is
potentially more space for offshore wind. So, the new situation is: a maximum capacity for
offshore wind of ~780 MW (at maximum strike price and supposing no other technology obtains
CfD). Due to competition from other technologies, especially from dedicated biomass with CHP,
the estimated capacity left for offshore wind is just ~600 MW.
With this last announcement, the situation has improved considerably, but not enough. As the
estimation of budget left for offshore wind is around 600 MW, there is space for just one of the
projects and big projects will have to reduce capacity.
The 23rd October, Galloper project is abandoned due to the “difficulties in raising finance in time
to meet government rules” [71]. A week later, Iberdrola says that “was being forced to scale back
its proposed 1.2 gigawatt (GW) wind farm off the coast of East Anglia in order that its total
annual subsidy requirement would be less than £235m” [72].
The bidding process does not take place during the expected window (i.e. December 2-9) and all
the process is delayed due to appeals of the different participants. The 28th January of 2015,
DECC announces an increase on Pot 2 budget of £25m [73]. It means an increase around 90100 MW of offshore capacity, which benefits larger projects. In addition, new bidding dates are
announced, the new bidding window is from 29th of January to the 4th of February.
Winners are announced on 26th of February and there are two awarded offshore wind projects
[74]:

East Anglia One: capacity of 714 MW and CfD price of £119.89/MWh

Neart na Gaoithe: capacity of 448 MW and CfD price of £114.39/MWh
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 119
These prices are a significant reduction from the £150-160/MWh offered by the previous subsidy
mechanism.
7.3 Offshore wind industry evolution
In the meantime, the offshore wind industry is evolving rapidly and becoming more competitive.
There are different best practices and techniques in the industry that are contributing to this
competitiveness improvement. The followings are the most relevant ones:
a) Building larger wind farms
As Table 7.7 shows, the newest offshore wind farms have larger capacities (e.g. London Array,
West of Duddon Sand and Greater Gabbard) and projects currently under development are even
larger (e.g. East Anglia One, Inch Cape, Rampion).
Table 7.7: Sample of relevant UK offshore wind farms and projects [4coffshore]
Building larger wind farms implies some benefits on cost reductions. From one side, there are
some costs that do not depend on the capacity installed (e.g. design and development costs,
offshore substation, mobilization and demobilization cost of vessels, etc.), and, as a
consequence, a larger wind farm would have lower cost per MW. From the other side, it enables
taking advantage of economy of scales. For example, a developer who is planning to build a
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 120
wind farm of 1,000 MW may have more relative negotiation power than other one developing a
300 MW wind farm, and he would, presumably, obtain more competitive prices.
A good example of developing larger wind farms to obtain cost reductions is the case of East
Anglia One. Initially, they were planning to build a 1,200 MW wind farm and expected to have big
economies of scale. As seen in the previous point, Iberdrola had to shrink East Anglia One´s
capacity from the initial 1,200 MW due to an insufficient CfD budget. Mr Anderson, head of
Scottish Power (Iberdrola´s subsidiary in UK), stated the following after the budget
announcement: “Our belief is if you drove the process to do projects of that size and scale (over
1 GW) you would drive the costs down harder and faster. If you push the projects down to
smaller size and scale, we don´t think you will get the cost reduction coming through the industry
as quickly as you could” [75].
b) Using larger and more powerful turbines
As it occurs in onshore wind turbines, offshore turbines are becoming more powerful with time.
In July 2013, the London array wind farm was fully commissioned. It was the biggest offshore
wind farm until the moment and 175 Siemens WTGs of 3.6 MW were used. Nowadays, the
biggest commercial turbine is being produced by MHI Vestas and has a capacity of 8 MW and
there are turbines of 10 MW being developed by several manufacturers. Table 7.8 shows some
of the current larger commercial WTG, as well as, the model employed by the London Array
wind farm.
Table 7.8: Sample of relevant WTG models [4coffshore]
For a same capacity wind farm, CAPEX and OPEX are reduced by using larger turbines as well
as the load factor is increased. If turbines are bigger and the wind farm capacity does not
change, the number of WTGs is reduced. It means a reduction in the number of substructures
and foundations used, bringing reductions in CAPEX. In the meantime, O&M costs are reduced
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 121
as there are fewer turbines. Finally, the load factor is increased due to a smaller weak effect. In
the study made by BVG associates (see Figure 7.6), CAPEX and OPEX reductions are 3% and
26% respectively, and the load factor increases by a 3% if the turbine size is 8 MW instead of 4
MW.
Figure 7.6: Effect of larger turbines in different aspects [“Future renewable energy costs: offshore wind”. BVG
associates - 2014]
c) Moving to better wind locations while costs keep affordable
One of the most important factors to have a competitive wind farm is wind characteristics of the
site. So, the election of the site is extremely important. However, better wind conditions are often
given further from the shore which, in the meantime, usually means deeper waters. By the end
of 2014, the average water depth of offshore wind farms in the Europe was 22.4 m and the
average distance to the coast was 32.9 km [76]. There are projects announced in water depths
up to 215 m and distance from the shore up to 200 km [77]. Table 7.9 shows the average wind
speeds, distance to shore and depth of some UK wind farms.
It seems logical that regulators and developers should join efforts in order to harvest first those
locations close to shore and with good wind characteristics. This way, the combination of good
winds and low costs would enable the construction of competitive wind farms. However, these
locations are limited and there is the need of going to deeper waters further from the shore and
this is generating two problems:

Traditional substructures are not suitable for deeper waters

The greater distance from the shore increases power transmission losses
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 122
Table 7.9: Wind and location characteristics of a sample of wind farms [4coffshore]
How is industry solving the deeper waters issue?
Substructures and foundations have to adapt and evolve in concordance with the trend of going
to deeper waters. From the monopiles and Gravity-Based Structures used in shallow waters,
substructures are evolving to space frame solutions (e.g. jackets, tri-piles and tripods), and is
likely that floating platforms are used in the future.
There are five main types of fixed substructures:
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 123
Table 7.10: Main characteristics for the different fixed substructures [based on “Wind in our Sails”, EWEA - 2011]
These substructures, except GBS, use piles as foundations. Suction caisson foundation is an
alternative to piles that is nowadays under development and testing. Its working mechanism
relies on two fundaments. First, its own weight, as in the GBS case, that gives stability to the
structure by using gravity. The other basis is suction, it takes out material from the inside of the
foundation creating a pressure differential that keeps the foundation attached to the seabed (see
Figure 7.7). The main advantages are that installation is easier and less expensive equipment is
required (e.g. cost reductions around 34% could be obtained [78]). Some of the companies
developing this technology are Dong Energy, E.ON, Statkraft and Statoil.
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 124
Figure 7.7: Illustrative of Suction Caisson working principle ["Foundations for Offshore Wind Turbines", University of
Oxford - Dec. 2014]
Monopiles have traditionally and are expected to dominate the market due to their simplicity and
low costs. Their deployment will be limited by deeper water sites where monopiles are not
technically feasible. Jackets should grow in these more challenging sites. They are already the
chosen type of substructure in projects under development: jackets are the most probable
solution for projects that have applied for CfD in the first allocation round and have depths larger
than 30 m (e.g. East Anglia One, Seagreen Alpha, Inch Cape or Neart na Gaoithe).
Nowadays, all commercial offshore wind farms under development are using fixed
substructures. However, the use of fixed substructures is limited to water depths not higher then
50-60 m and there are many countries where the number of shallow water sites is limited (e.g.
Mediterranean, Atlantic basins and Norway; 66% of the North Sea has a water depth between
50 m and 220 m). So, floating structures are being developed. There are three main primary
types [79]: tensioned-leg platform (TLP), semi-submergible and the spar buoy (see Figure 7.8).

Spar buoy: a large cylindrical buoy that stabilizes the wind turbine using ballast. The
center of gravity is much lower in the water than the center of buoyancy. Whereas the
lower parts of the structure are heavy, the upper parts are usually empty elements near
the surface, raising the center of buoyancy

TLP: tensioned mooring lines are attached to a semi-submerged structure and are
anchored on the seabed to add buoyancy and stability
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 125

Semi-submergible: combining the main principles of the two previous designs, a semi
submerged structure is added to reach the necessary stability
Figure 7.8: Illustrative of floating substructure ["Deep Water. The next step for offshore wind energy", EWEA - July
2013]
There are already 5 floating prototypes connected to the grid and 35 projects under
development. The followings are some examples among those:
Table 7.11: Sample of relevant floating project and prototypes ["Deep Water. The next step for offshore wind energy",
EWEA - July 2013]
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 126
Table 7.12: Pictures of projects in Table 7.11 ["Deep Water. The next step for offshore wind energy", EWEA - July
2013]
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 127
How is industry solving the greater transmission losses due to longer export cables?
As offshore wind farms are built further from shore and have larger capacities, minimizing
transmission losses is becoming of increasing relevance. Electrical transmission systems have
changed considerably since the first offshore wind farms. At the beginning, those wind farms
close to shore were directly connected to the onshore electrical grid at Medium Voltage.
However, the maximum power that could be exported by one cable was of the order of 30-40
MW and large project needed a large number of cables [80]. So, as wind farms started moving
away from shore the chosen solution has been high voltage AC systems. An offshore substation
is installed in the wind farm and it converts power from medium voltage (power is generated in
medium voltage in WTGs) to high voltage. Then, power is transmitted using a small number of
high voltage cables (typically in the range of 120 to 220 kV). Table 7.13 shows some of the most
relevant offshore wind farms with an HVAC connection.
Table 7.13: Main electrical transmission characteristics for sample of projects [“Offshore Wind Transmission Study,
Final Report”, ESS Group, Inc – September 2014]
Nevertheless, AC transmission lines have some limitations [81]:

Charging current and related thermal ratings of the cables

Systems voltage issues due to the use of long cables

Line losses due to length

System stability issues during AC cable faults during cable operation
These limitations are playing in favor of HVDC transmission as wind farms become larger and
are further from shore. HVDC avoids the large charging currents causing energy losses in 50/60
Hz AC cable systems. However, it has two main barriers. First, it is an immature technology with
lack of widespread application. It has suffered from various complications during the last years
that have slowed the shift to HVDC (e.g. Siemens has suffered from significant write-offs for
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 128
over-budget transmission HVDC projects) [82]. The second barrier is the AC/DC converters.
These converter stations are very large, expensive and present some logistical challenges due
to their size and weight. Overall, HVDC installations are thought to be cost-effective for projects
of around 500 MW with a cable route of around 100 km [83], although these figures are rather
uncertain and larger capacities might be required. Figure 7.9 shows an example of the structure
of a HVDC system.
Figure 7.9: HVDC transmission structure [“Offshore Wind Transmission Study, Final Report”, ESS Group, Inc – Sept.
2014]
d) Making wind farm execution more efficient, effective and reliable
The objectives of every developer during the construction phase of a wind farm are to guarantee
the following three aspects:

There are not cost overruns

Execution goes in time

Quality of installation
As it is an immature industry, the construction of an offshore wind farm faces several risks.
These risks can have a significant impact on project´s profitability (see Table 7.14) and it is
important to manage them correctly. Buffers are introduced in the construction schedule to
handle unexpected delays and contingencies are added to CAPEX previsions in order to make
more accurate cost estimations. Buffers have a cost (i.e. later generation of incomes, personnel
and vessels waiting for the next phase to start, etc.), but they are necessary for the success of a
project. So, there is a trade-off between guaranteeing buffers are long enough and minimizing
costs.
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 129
Table 7.14: Impact of sample of relevance risks on profitability [A.T. Kearney experience]
As a consequence, it is important to have vast experience and the required capacities in order to
build a wind farm successfully at the lower possible costs. For example, DONG, which is the
leading developer in the offshore wind industry (i.e. 24.1% of the European offshore wind
capacity by the end of 2014 [84]), haves enough experience and capacities to reduce buffers
considerably and make very accurate estimations of CAPEX. They have an experienced team of
engineers and managers that guarantee the certainty of their calculations and cost estimations.
A new entrant to the wind offshore industry, however, would need to leave longer buffers and
larger contingencies due to the reduced experience and capacities. Furthermore, the new
entrant should subcontract these lacking capacities to another company.
The construction of an offshore wind farm is a very complex work. There are many components
and each component has different installation stages. So, developers often have to subcontract
other companies to develop certain tasks. In addition, there are several interfaces between the
different tasks (see Figure 7.10) and it is crucial to manage those interfaces correctly in order to
reduce delays and cost overruns. Going to the extreme cases, there would be two types of
subcontracting. The first one would consist on subcontracting all tasks to the same experienced
contractor. The subcontracted company would manage the whole wind farm construction and
the developer would not need to have especial capacities. This option, however, would result
being quite expensive. The second type is subcontracting each task to a different company. It
implies that the developer would have to manage those interfaces and would need to know how
to do it, but they would usually mean fewer costs. So, developers have to take the decision
between having fewer costs or having lower uncertainty in execution. This decision is often
conditioned by funding institutions. They usually tend to prefer the first option, as the responsible
for the management of the construction is an experienced company and reduces project risks. In
the contrary, companies tend to prefer the second option as it means less costs. It consists on a
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 130
negotiation with the bank, and depending on how experienced the developer is, banks will
accept more or less packetized subcontracting.
Figure 7.10: Interfaces between tasks during the construction of a wind farm [A.T. Kearney experience]
Finally, it is very important to have good information about the composition of soil and weather
characteristics of the location (i.e. wind speed at sea level and wave height). While the first one
would prevent from unexpected problems and delays during the piling and foundation installation
tasks, good weather measurements would help to accurate estimations of vessel operability and
make more certain estimations of installation tasks durations.
e) Having a more stable regulatory framework
Stability on the regulatory framework is an important aspect to contribute in LCOE reductions. A
regulatory framework with few or no changes gives developers visibility and certainty of which
the subsidies and regulation will be. It will motivate developers to start new projects and, in the
meantime, it also reduces institutional risks, improving projects bankability. A clear example of
this is the case of East Anglia One. They were intending to construct a 1,200 MW wind farm in
order to take advantage of big economies of scales. The change of support mechanism from
ROCs to CfD and the different changes on CfD budget have made Iberdrola to reduce the size.
In addition, there are usually some requirements that have to been fulfilled in order to obtain
subsidies. These requirements often mean some extra costs that could be avoided if there were
fewer. For instance, one of the aspects that the Supply Chain Plan should demonstrate in order
to be approved and be able to bid for CfD was high local content, this is, the development and
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 131
construction of the wind farm should create wealth in the UK. It obligates, for example, wind
turbine manufacturers to open a new factory in the UK. As a consequence, turbines are more
expensive that if the manufacturer had an only factory to supply all Europe.
f) Reducing O&M costs
While the total CAPEX for a 500 MW is in the range of 1,750-2,000 million €, OPEX is around
100-120 million € per year [85]. Considering that the predicted life of an offshore wind farm is
around 25 years, O&M costs are a relevant aspect to take into account.
BVG associates predict that the larger cost reductions on a wind farm will be given by OPEX
improvements. They estimate that OPEX will reduce by a 15-20% in 2025 due to several
technology innovations [86]. One of the mentioned innovations is the direct drive technology
(see point 4.3.1). It removes the gearbox resulting in a simpler drive train with fewer mechanical
parts. Gearboxes are usually one of the components with higher failure rates in a wind turbine.
Additionally, O&M synergies between wind farms that are close to each other could reduce
considerably these costs. For example, having a vessel for the maintenance of just one wind
farm can result in being too costly. So, sharing this vessel and its crew between two, three or
more wind farms would mean significant reductions in OPEX.
g) Bits & pieces
There are many other things that can be done in order to minimize development, construction
and operating costs, every small detail counts in the process of maximizing profitability. An
example of this is the dilemma that surges due to wind farms´ layout.
The layout of an offshore wind farm is designed with the objective of maximizing the load factor
for a given site and the number of turbines. Ideally, the annual output energy of a wind farm
would be the production of one turbine times the number of turbines. However, it is slightly
smaller. When wind goes through a WTG, it losses a bit of energy, so the turbine behind will
have a weaker wind. This effect is known as weak effect.
There are two things that can be done to reduce the weak effect to the minimum. The first one is
to use the whole area of the site and place turbines as far as possible from each other. Although
it may seem possible, there may be cases in which this is not the chosen option. For instance, if
a site has the consent to build 1,000 MW and the developer aims to build a 500 MW wind farm, it
has to take the decision between making the 500 MW wind farm as profitable as possible
(occupying the whole area and maximizing the load factor) or leaving open the possibility for a
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 132
second 500 MW phase sacrificing profitability of the first phase (occupying just the half of the
area and maximizing the weak effect).
The second one consists on taking into account site´s wind characteristics. In order to minimize
the weak effect, wind turbines do not have to be aligned in the direction in which wind comes
from more often.
7.4 Learnings
The renewable affordability problem is a fact that is not only happening in the UK, other
European countries are also beginning to doubt about its sustainability and there have been
some changes in regulation. This reaction is not surprising as it is true that renewable energy
results being expensive. For instance, in the case of offshore wind, operators are earning over
£150/MWh with the RO mechanism when the pool price moves usually below £70/MWh.
However, subsidies are the only way for now to expand renewable energy and reduce the
environmental impact of human´s energy consumption.
There are some support mechanisms than result less costly to consumers. The comparison
between RO and CfD is a good example of this. Awarding subsidies by a competitive process
forces developers to be creative and apply the latest techniques in order to reduce costs as
much as possible. In addition, just the best projects are granted a CfD contract and most costly
projects are discarded. As a consequence, the first CfD allocation round has managed to reduce
offshore wind´s revenues per MWh from over £150/MWh to £115-120/MWh. It is a real success
as it means a reduction higher than a 25% in a very short period of time. The UK has managed
to subsidy renewable energy while having a reduced impact in the consumer.
In the meantime, the offshore wind industry is evolving very fast. There are plenty techniques
used to reduce cost and reach better wind locations. It is translating in LCOE reductions and
competitiveness increase, but it is still an immature technology with plenty of development and
construction risks.
Nevertheless, there are still many things to improve that would contribute in faster LCOE
reductions. A greater harmony between developers and regulator seems necessary, and
cooperation of both sides would result on a faster technology evolution. There are many
examples for this. For instance, encouraging developers to build larger wind farms in order to
take advantage of economies of scale. It would likely contribute in significant cost reductions for
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 133
the consumer. Or, developers and regulator could jointly work to encourage wind farm
construction in best wind locations. Finally, eliminating some regulatory requirements (e.g. local
content) would significantly avoid some extra costs.
To sum up, there are ways of supporting renewable energy while reducing the economic impact
on the consumer. So, adopting a well-designed support framework is crucial in order to launch
renewable generation and have a mechanism that lasts for long and gives stability to
developers. UK´s case is a good reference for other countries to learn how renewable support
can be maintained with a reduced impact on the consumer.
Chapter 7 | Practical case 1 134
Chapter 8
Practical case 2: Can distributed
generation threaten the status quo of
utilities in Spain?
Among all the drivers explained in chapter 5, special attention should be paid to prosumers and
distributed generation, even more in the Spanish case where the abundant solar resource
makes economic fundamentals more attractive. Furthermore, as seen in chapter 6, selfconsumption would have considerable effects on the electric sector and on utilities.
Grid parity is likely to be reached during this decade and DG deployment can be exponential. In
this chapter, the main barriers for DG expansion have been identified and a model has been
built in order to make estimations of DG adoption in 2020.
8.1 Profitability analysis
In the electric sector decisions historically have been taken in a centralized way and thinking in
what the best option for the sustainability and reliability of the system was. In distributed
generation, however, the decision is taken based on an individual profitability analysis and
personal interests may not be aligned with system´s interest. So, profitability is not compared
with other generation technologies but with the grid electricity price, i.e. grid parity. There are two
types of grid parities: static and dynamic grid parity.
Static grid parity happens when the levelized cost of generation (LCOE) of PV is equal to the
electricity price. It is a snapshot of the competitive position and the relative strength of PV.
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 135
Static grid parity has already been reached in 2014 in Seville, it will be obtained in Madrid
between 2015 and 2016 and by 2017 in Bilbao (see Figure 8.11).
Figure 8.1: Static grid parity for different Spanish regions (Bilbao, Madrid and Seville)
Dynamic grid parity (also known as investment parity) happens when the lifetime PV-related
project costs are equal to the total savings generated. It is a movie over a relevant period of the
competitive position. A 100 kW system installed in 2015 would have a pay-back period of 11-12
years in Bilbao, 10-11 years in Madrid and around 9 years in Seville (see Table 8.1).
Table 8.1: Dynamic grid parity for Bilbao, Madrid and Seville
1
100kW PV system and elec. prices for 20 MWh < Consumption < 500 MWh
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 136
8.2 Market volume projection
Distributed generation´s installed capacity could reach up to 11.4 GW by 2020 if net-metering
was approved. It would mean a 6.5% of the total contracted capacity1 in 2014. Generation would
be ~15 TWh which is around the 6% of the energy demand in 2014. These numbers would
significantly reduce to 1.8 GW and 2.5 TWh in the case of back-up toll (~1% in both cases).
Finally, figures for the no regulation case would be 5.8 GW and 7.5 TWh (3.3% and 3%
respectively).
Figure 8.2: Installed capacity and energy generation 2020 predictions of distributed generation
8.2.1 Methodology
There can be different possible approaches to estimate the distributed generation market
volume in 2020, e.g. calculate the potential available area for distributed generation or calculate
the potential number of prosumers. In this work, the second approach has been considered the
most suitable one as it gives a clearer and more realistic vision of the situation. The next
methodology has been followed: segmentation of the different types of electricity consumers,
identification and quantification of potential barriers for distributed generation in each of the
segments and application of these barriers over the total amount of electricity consumers in each
segment in order to obtain the prediction of prosumers in 2020.
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 137
Five different segments have been identified depending on their type of activity. Four of them
include businesses and companies, while the last one is formed by residential consumers.
CNAE´s classification of professional activities has been use as a reference on the segmentation
[87]:

Agriculture: it covers the range of activity numbers 0XXX

Energy intensive industry: it includes from 20XX to 25XX activity numbers

Energy non-intensive industry: activity numbers in the range of 1XXX and 26XX-29XX

Other activities: it includes the following range of activities: 3XXX-9XXX. Next references
to this group will be made as Commerce, as this activity predominates over the rest in
this group

Residential consumer: it includes both, apartments inside a building and individual
houses
The segment of energy intensive industry has been excluded from calculations as they have low
electricity prices (i.e. under 8 cent€/kWh in 20142) compared with solar PV LCOE (i.e. over 9
cent€/kWh by 2020). In addition, secondary houses are not going to be taken into account in the
residential segment as they will not be profitable in the short and medium term. They currently
have pay-back periods larger than 35 years (see Investment pay-back period point).
Four main barriers for the expansion of distributed generation have been identified: space,
financial, mindset and regulatory barriers. Figure 8.3 shows an example of the methodology
employed.
Figure 8.3: Illustrative example of methodology
1
During tariff period 1
2
Industrial consumers and consumption < 70,000 MWh, Eurostat
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 138

Space barrier: distributed generation has one limitation on space. Even if a company or
an individual have the willingness of self-generating, they may not have space for the
installation of the PV panels. This barrier has especial relevance in cities, where the
available surface for DG is mainly limited to rooftops. This barrier will imply a reduction of
the accessible market for distributed generation

Financial barrier: this barrier covers three aspects
o
Liquidity: there may be people or companies who do not even consider selfconsuming as they do not have enough money to buy and install a PV system.
This barrier is taken into account as a reduction of the accessible market
o
Profitability: it is related to the static grid parity, comparison between electricity
prices and PV system LCOE. Potential prosumers will look for a certain
profitability of their investment before installing self-consumption systems
o
Investment pay-back period: it is related to dynamic grid parity, comparison
between the pay-back period and the rotation rate. In case the pay-back period
is larger than the rotation rate, it may make no sense to invest as money is not
going to be recovered

Mindset barrier: as explained in chapter 5, solar PV is a relatively new technology and
people may be reluctant to it. The impact of this barrier is taken into account combined
with profitability

Regulatory barrier: it will affect considerably the DG expansion as it can worsen or
improve its financials. Three cases are going to be modelled in order to simulate the
possible changes in regulation: no regulation case (neither favorable nor contrary
regulation), back-up toll case (contrary regulation) and net-metering case (favorable
regulation)
Finally, once the estimation of prosumers is done, this figure is going to be transformed into
estimated power capacity and estimated generation. This process is developed by assigning a
certain capacity for each segment.
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 139
Figure 8.4: Illustrative example of the estimation process
Additionally, as the LCOE of a PV installation depends greatly on the site´s solar resource,
Spain has been divided into four regions according to the global horizontal irradiance (GHI) (see
Figure 8.5). GHI is the sum of the direct normal irradiance (DNI) and the diffuse horizontal
irradiance (DHI) and it is the more appropriate measure in the case of PV panels. Regions are
North (Galicia, Asturias, Castilla y León, Cantabria, País Vasco, Navarra and La Rioja), Centre
(Comunidad de Madrid, Cataluña, Aragón, Comunidad Valenciana and Castilla la Mancha),
South (Andalucía, Extremadura, Murcia, Ceuta and Melilla) and Islands (Baleares and Islas
Canarias).
Figure 8.5: regions and GHI by region [NASA Surface meteorology and Solar Energy database]
Each of the barriers is going to be discussed deeply in the following points.
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 140
a) Space barrier
This is one of the main barriers and probably the one which reduces more the number of
potential prosumers. There are many businesses, companies or people that do not have even
the choice to self-consume due to lack of space. In addition, this barrier will also serve to
eliminate all those activities that are very unlikely to self-consume due to their characteristics
(e.g. forestry).
Space barrier has especial impact on the commerce and the residential community segments.
These two segments have more presence in town and cities than the other segments. They may
be located in vertically erected building, sharing the reduced rooftop space with the other
electricity consumers in the same building. The agriculture segment has enough space for a
ground mounted installation, while the industry and residential house segments usually have
enough rooftop area, or they may even have the possibility for a ground mounted installation.
Table 8.2: Space availability by segment
In order to quantify the impact of this barrier, the activities of each segment that would have the
potential to install a DG system have been selected (see Table 8.3). This way, those activities
that do not have enough space or are not considered to be suitable for self-consumption are
discarded. Additionally, only companies and businesses with annual revenues over 100 k€ have
been selected in order to reject possible enterprises without activity. In the case of the activities
46 and 47, this figure has been increased to 500 k€. These activities have greater presence in
urban locations, so a higher limit is taken in order to avoid small businesses inside buildings.
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 141
Table 8.3: Selected activities by segment
In the case of the residential community segment, this impact is quantified by calculating the
equivalent number of consumers by community that could have space for a PV installation in the
roof. For this purpose, communities have been divided into two groups: communities with two or
four apartments per floor. So, the rooftop space of each community will be calculated as (1) and
the number of consumers per community as (2):
The average size of apartments in Spain [88] is in the range of 76-90 m2, while the common
areas are assumed to have 15 m2 on average. As seen in chapter 4, the area needed for c-Si
panels is 7 m2 per kW and each installation is assumed to be of 3 kW. The available rooftop
surface for PV panel installation has considered being around 45-50%. There are some
buildings with flat roofs that have almost all the rooftop surface available for DG (see Figure 8.6
A). There are others, however, with the roof tilted (see Figure 8.6 B). Thus, they could only
install PV panels on the side facing south. In addition, there are obstacles (e.g. chimneys)
limiting the area in both cases. Assuming an availability of 70-75% and 25-30% respectively, the
average availability has been taken as the arithmetic mean of both.
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 142
Figure 8.6: Pictures of two type of rooftops. A (left) and B (right)
Finally, the number of equivalent installation per community that would have space are 3.3
(communities of two apartments per floor) and 6.3 (communities of four apartments per floor).
b) Financial barrier
Liquidity
Consumers fulfilling the next criteria will be considered to have enough liquidity in order to afford
the installation of a DG system, while the rest will be discarded:

Monthly incomes per home of at least 2,000 € for residential consumers [89]. It is
considered that people with less incomes may have financial difficulties to afford a 3 kW
installation (~6,500 €)

The last two years with positive cash flow for companies for businesses with annual
revenues below 50 million €. Hence, only companies that have been generating money
during the last two years are considered

All companies and businesses with annual revenues over 50 million €, as they are
considered to have access to external funding even if they do not have enough liquidity
by their own
Profitability
A study carried by Ofgem [90] about customer engagements states that the 16% of the
consumers would change of electricity supplier if they had annual savings of £0-50, another 35%
would do it if this number was £51-100, a 34% if £101-200 and the resting 14% for +£201. As
the average energy bill for residential consumers in the UK is £587 [91], the resulting adoption
curve as a function of the percentage of savings is given by Figure 8.7 (it has been extrapolated
by a fifth order polynomial function in order to have a continuous curve).
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 143
This curve is going to be the basis for the estimation of the DG adoption as a function of
profitability. In this work, profitability plays the role of savings and is calculated as the percentage
difference between electricity price and PV LCOE.
Figure 8.7: Adoption curve depending on saving [based on “Customer Engagement with the Energy Market –
Tracking Survey 2013”, Ofgem – June 2013]
Figure 8.8 shows the different elements that have to be taken into account during the profitability
calculation. These elements are described next. The LCOE has been calculated using an excel
model based on A.T. Kearney´s proprietary PV model.
Figure 8.8: Profitability dependence chart

Electricity price: it varies for the different segments. Each of the segments has been
associated to the access tariff that fits with its characteristics (i.e. Agriculture: 3.1 A,
Industry 3.1 A, Commerce: 3.0 A and Residential: 2.0 A - PVPC). In the case of PVPC,
the price per kWh is immediate as it is fixed by the government and had a value of
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 144
0.1241 €/kWh in 2014. However, calculating the price for tariffs 3.0A and 3.1A is more
complicated. These tariffs are divided into three periods and each period has its price. In
order to obtain an unique price per kWh, the solar profile has been compared to the three
periods and the percentage of energy generated on its period has been calculated. Then,
the average weighted price is obtained. The prices shown in Table 8.4 are the arithmetic
mean between prices in 2014 offered by Endesa and Gas Natural Fenosa. Figure 8.9
shows the solar profile and the period division for both tariffs.
Figure 8.9: Solar profile and period division for 3.0A and 3.1A tariffs [based on MINETUR]
Comparing the solar profile and period divisions in summer and winter, results for a 3.0A
consumer are that almost 60% of generation is done during period 2, almost 30% during
period 1 and the resting 10% in period 3. In the case of a 3.1A consumer, figures are
42.5% during period 1, 48% during period 2 and 10% during period 3. In order to obtain
an only price for each kWh consumed, the weighted average of prices is calculated using
the following formula:
Results are shown in the next table:
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 145
Table 8.4: Weighted average price calculation for 3.0A and 3.1A tariffs

Consumed generation: all the generated energy may not be consumed instantly. So,
unless the system has storage or net-metering is approved (see Regulatory barrier), the
electricity that is not consumed at the moment will be lost. The generation pattern and the
consumption profile for each segment have been compared. Ideally, the system can be
sized so that the generated power and the consumed power are equal during the peak
generation moment. Next figure shows the comparison between both profiles and the
percentage of energy consumed instantly.
Figure 8.10: Solar and consumption profile comparison [based on REE and MINETUR]

CAPEX and OPEX: inputs have been taken from A.T. Kearney´s PV model and some
have been reviewed and updated. Module price is one of the most relevant inputs. Its
price at utility scale is currently in the range of 0.48-0.52 €/Wp (0.52 €/Wp for European
and Chinese modules, 0.48 €/Wp for other Asian modules) [92]. It has been assumed
that residential prosumers could buy modules a 20% more cost than utilities, Commerce
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 146
and Agriculture segments a 15% and Industry a 10%. Some of the most important inputs
are shown in the next table:
Table 8.5: Sample of relevant LCOE model inputs
Investment pay-back period
This barrier is only considered in the residential case. The other segments are assumed to have
lower rotation rates and going deeper has been considered of reduced relevance. The impact of
this barrier has been calculated as the percentage of consumers that change of house before
the pay-back period. For the calculation, it has been assumed an electricity price of 0.1241
€/kWh in 2014 and an annual average growth of 2%.
Table 8.6: Calculation of investment pay-back period impact
Similarly, the pay-back period for secondary residential houses has been calculated. These
houses are usually located in sunny region and their usage is limited to holidays or some
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 147
weekends. So, in this case, South’s region irradiation is going to be used and two months of
usage per year are going to be assumed. It results in pay-back periods longer than 35 years.
c) Mindset barrier
Everyone has this barrier, in some cases it may be larger than in other ones, but it is always
present. The quantification of its impact is based on the idea that a higher profitability overcomes
this reluctance. So, it has been implemented as an extra percentage of the profitability
demanded for a given adoption, this is, a displacement of the adoption curve in Figure 8.11.
Three levels of reluctance have been defined. Each of these levels has associated an extra
percentage of profitability required: low (0 p.p.), medium (+5 p.p.) and high (+10 p.p.). The
resulting adoption curves are shown in the next figure:
Figure 8.11: Adoption curve for the different mindset barrier levels
Each of the segments and activities has been classified into one of the levels depending on their
predisposition to changes and new technology. The default level is set to be the medium level.
Some activities have been moved to the lower level due to greater affinity to technology (i.e. 61.
Telecommunications and 72. Scientific research and development). The residential community
segment has been moved to the higher level as it requires from the approval of the whole
community (There may be people with different affinities to PV and it could imply difficulties).
d) Regulatory barrier
Each of the cases is based in the energy policies taken in the different scenarios in chapter 5.
The three different cases and their implications on the model are shown next.
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 148

Case 1, no regulation: self-consumption is neither supported nor discouraged with tolls.
So, energy that is not consumed instantly is wasted. The impact has been modelled
applying the percentages in Figure 8.10 to the generated energy

Case 2, back-up toll: this case simulates the situation in which the draft RD announced in
July 2013 is approved. It has the following implications in the model:
o
As in the no regulation case, energy not consumed instantly is wasted
o
Each generated and consumed unit of energy is penalized with a toll. The toll
for the 3.0 A and 3.1 A tariffs is given in three periods. Methodology followed to
obtain a weighted average toll is the same as in the case of the electricity price.
Additionally, the draft RD considered self-consumption only those units under
100 kW. So, as the DG systems for the industry system are going to be larger
than 100 kW, there is no toll for the industrial segment
Table 8.7: Back-up toll by segment [based on Draft RD for self-consumption, July 2013]

Case 3, net-metering: It is assumed that each kWh introduced to the grid can be
consumed later without any cost. In the practice, net-metering would be comparable to a
DG system with storage. So, all the generated energy would be consumed, even if it is
not instantly. It has the following implications in the predictions:
o
The consumption profile is not taken into account in the LCOE model and all the
energy generated is consumed
o
As the grid acts like a storage system, the PV size does not have to match with
the consumption profile. Thus, a 50% more installed capacity is assumed per
each DG unit
e) Prosumer to MW and MWh conversion
As a result of applying the previously explained barriers, the predicted number of consumers is
obtained. This figure, however, is not representative of the threat that distributed generation
supposes to utilities. The last step consists on converting the number of self-consumer in
capacity and energy. This measure will give a more accurate idea of the impact of DG.
For this purpose, each segment has been assigned a kW per prosumer ratio. In the case of
Commerce segment, as it groups different kind of activities, it has been divided into three groups
and each of the groups has its own kW per consumer ratio (see Table 8.8).
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 149
Table 8.8: Capacity per installation by segment
Finally, the capacity to energy conversion depends on three factors. The first one is the solar
irradiance of each region. So, each region has a kW to kWh conversion. Secondly, large
installations usually have better performance factors than smaller ones. As a consequence, the
residential segment has a slightly smaller kWh per kW ratio. And finally, it depends on the
regulatory case. For instance, in the net-metering case all the generated energy is consumed,
but in no regulation and back-up toll cases, percentages in Figure 8.10 have to been applied.
Table 8.9 shows the kW to kWh conversion taking into account just the first two factors.
Table 8.9: Capacity to Energy conversion table
f) Summary
Figure 8.12 and Figure 8.13 show the flow diagram of the explained methodology. Steps in
Figure 8.12 are common in all regulatory cases. Steps in Figure 8.13, however, are different
depending on the regulatory case. So, first steps have been done just once, while the last steps
have to be repeated for each regulatory case.
Two sources have been used to determine the initial number of homes and companies. In the
case of the residential segment, data has been taken from the Encuesta Continua de Hogares
20131 elaborated by INE (Spanish statistics national institute). In the case of the other segments,
the SABI database of companies has been used.
1
Continuous home survey 2013
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 150
Figure 8.12: Flow diagram of methodology (1/2). Common for all regulatory cases
Figure 8.13: Flow diagram of methodology (2/2). Repeated for each regulatory case
8.2.2 Detailed projections
Results are presented from different perspectives in order to gain in clarity and make easier their
understanding. Final results for each of the regulatory cases are shown first. This is the
adequate snapshot to identify which segments and regions have the greater potential for
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 151
distributed generation. Then, intermediate results of the procedure are presented for each
segment. This photo shows the effect different barriers have on each segment.
8.2.2.1 By regulatory case
Case 1: No regulation
Distributed generation has the larger potential in the commercial segment. From the 5.7 GW of
installed capacity, more than the half corresponds to this segment. In the residential segment,
although the predictions point almost 400 thousand prosumer (85%), they only account for the
20% of the installed capacity and 19% of the consumed energy.
The region with greater adoption is the Centre region with more than 45% of the installed
capacity. South region occupies a second place with more than 36%. This results show that, as
stated in chapter 5, self-consumption would start first in the sunniest regions. The share of
Islands region is reduced due to the small number of people and companies they have. The
North region, however, has the lowest adoption (7.6%) due to the lack of solar resource. So, one
thing can be concluded: even if grid parity will be reached in all Spanish regions, the obtained
profitability is not good enough in less solar irradiance locations and it will take longer than 2020
to have significant adoptions.
Figure 8.14: Snapshot of key results for Case 1
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 152
Case 2: Back-up toll
One main conclusion can be derived looking at Figure 8.15: the back-up toll would have a very
impactful discouraging effect, i.e. installed capacity less than a third than in the previous case
(and it would be significantly lower if the industry segment was excluded). In the residential
segment, this toll would make DG totally unprofitable; in the commerce segment installed
capacity would reduce to less than a 20%; and in the industry segment, it would not have
segment as installations over 100 kW would not be considered self-consumption and would not
have a toll.
Figure 8.15: Snapshot of key results for Case 2
Case 3: Net-metering
Net-metering would mean a real impulse for distributed generation: installed capacity would be
almost double than in the no regulation case (i.e. 11.4 GW). It would specially boost the
residential segment. The reason is simple: while other segment´s electricity consumption peak
matches almost perfectly with the solar profile, it is shifted to three hours later and the
coincidence between consumption and solar profile is not the 100% as in the other cases. So, as
in net-metering the grid works as a storage system for the prosumer, all the previously wasted
energy is now consumed and profitability improves.
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 153
Figure 8.16: Snapshot of key results for Case 3
8.2.2.2 By segment
Next, the estimation processes for each of the segments are shown. As it can be seen in the
different figures, space barrier is the barrier that has the greatest impact followed by profitability
and liquidity barriers.
Agriculture
Figure 8.17: Step-by-step results of the prediction procedure (1/4) Agriculture segment
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 154
Industry
Figure 8.18: Step-by-step results of the prediction procedure (2/4) Industry segment
Commerce
Figure 8.19: Step-by-step results of the prediction procedure (3/4) Commerce segment
Residential
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 155
Figure 8.20: Step-by-step results of the prediction procedure (4/4) Residential segment
Chapter 8 | Practical case 2 156
Chapter 9
Conclusions
Disruption in the electric sector is imminent and unstoppable. It started in the last decade with
green energy policies driving the rally towards renewable energy (e.g. already a 43% of
electricity consumption in Spain). Even if there are certain doubts about the affordability of this
transition, the process keeps moving forward. Booming innovation in renewable is gradually
improving its competitiveness. So the moment in which green energy policies will not be the
main driver for renewable expansion will arrive for sure. Moreover, even if regulation tries to
oppose renewable expansion, solid economic fundamentals will enable the deployment. The
case of distributed generation is a good example. A back-up toll has been announced in Spain to
retribute the grids and create barriers to distributed generation. Moreover, the toll increases the
incentives of “prosumers” to install storage capacity, thus further fostering innovation and
investment in DG.
The benefits of renewable energy are clear: reducing environmental impact and dependence on
fossil fuels and foreign energy. Nevertheless, green energy policies have considerably increased
the final consumer’s energy bill in Spain and in Europe as a whole. So, if regulators have the aim
to keep subsidizing renewable energy, they have to find the way of doing it with the minimum
impact on the consumer. Europe is realizing how to balance these two objectives at a minimum
cost (though probably after significant investments have been committed). For instance, the UK
has successfully moved to a more efficient mechanism with their last energy reform. They have
managed to foster best practices and techniques in the renewable industry by establishing a
competitive budget allocation process. As a result, the new mechanism is driving LCOE
reductions while keeping renewable support affordable.
Finally, the disruption of the electric system is a challenge for electric utilities as it will affect their
P&L. Traditionally, the electric sector has been a profitable business in which there were several
barriers for new entrants. This is about to change and utilities have two alternatives: either they
try to prevent disruption from happening by establishing barriers, or they radically reshape their
Chapter 9 | Conclusions 157
business model to sustain their positioning in the new paradigm of electric sector. This project
has shown enough evidence about disruption being unstoppable. In the long run, barriers will
have a very limited effect and it would imply losing ground against competitors. There is
therefore only one choice for utilities: to reshape their business model. Utilities have to adapt or
die. Several utilities have already started this reshaping process. As previously discussed, E.ON
has placed a bet on these trend, and has decided to focus on renewable energy, networks and
distributed generation, spinning-off their conventional generation business. Some other
European utilities might replicate this move in order to sustain their profitability and gain
competitive advantage. But in addition to challenges, there are also attractive opportunities that
utilities will need to capture. Storage, electrification of energy consumption, and the electric
vehicle in particular, could place utility companies next to the client, in the center of the new
energy paradigm.
Chapter 9 | Conclusions 158
Annex: Shortlist of energy start-ups and
companies
The following table shows the list of the start-ups and companies that have been selected to be
analyzed during the project due to having relevant innovative technologies:
Technology
Start-up/Company
Country
Generation
Photovoltaic
Solar
CSP
si-PV
Beacon Solar Energy
USA
si-PV
EverGreenSolar
China
si-PV
Enphase Energy
USA
si-PV
SunEdison
USA
si-PV
SunPower
USA
si-PV
tenKSolar
USA
Thin-film PV
Anwell technologies
Thin-film PV
Ascent Solar
USA
Thin-film PV
First Solar
USA
Thin-film PV
Solar Frontier
Thin-film PV
Xunlight Corporation
CPV
Soitec
France
CPV
Suncore Photovoltaic Technology
China
CPV
Zytech
Spain
Organic PV
Heliatek
Hong Kong
Japan
USA
Germany
Silicon gas made PV Solexel
Parabolic trough
and Solar Tower
Abengoa Solar
USA
Spain
Parabolic trough
Sener Group
Spain
Parabolic trough
Solar Millennium
Solar Tower
BrigthSource Energy
USA
Solar Tower
eSolar
USA
Solar Tower
SolarReserve
USA
Solar Tower
Torresol Energy
Spain
Linear Fresnel
Novatec Solar
Germany
Germany
Annex | 159
Wind
Less established
technologies
Conventional generation
Onshore wind
Onshore wind
Onshore wind
Onshore wind
Onshore wind
Onshore wind
Onshore wind
Onshore/Offshore
wind
Onshore/Offshore
wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
Offshore wind
High Altitude Wind
Power
High Altitude Wind
Power
High Altitude Wind
Power
High Altitude Wind
Power
High Altitude Wind
Power
Geothermal
Geothermal
Ocean Energy
Ocean Energy
Ocean Energy
Ocean Energy
Ocean Energy
CCS
Fission
Nuclear Fusion
Nuclear Fusion
AML
Angle Wind
Atlantic Bearing Services
Boulder WindPower
ChapDrive
Enercon
Skyacht Aircraft
USA
Norway
USA
USA
Norway
Germany
USA
Dong Energy
Denmark
Vestas
Alstom
Blue H
E.ON
Hexicon
IDEOL
Nass & Wind
Principle Power
Samsung
Senvion
Statoil
The Golsten Associates
Altaeros Energies
Ampyx Power
Denmark
France
UK
Germany
Sweden
France
France
USA
South Korea
Germany
Norway
USA
USA
Netherlands
KiteGen
Italy
Makani Power
USA
SkySails Power
Ecoforest
Green Energy Group
AWS Ocean Energy
Oceanlinx
OPT ocean power technologies
Pelamis wave power
Wave Dragon
SaskPower
Generation IV International Forum
ITER
Lockheed Martin
Germany
Spain
Norway
UK
Australia
USA
UK
Denmark
USA
International
International
USA
Annex | 160
Storage
Hydrogen
Hydrogen
Altergy Systems
Ballard
École Polytechnique Fédérale de
Hydrogen
Lausanne
Chemical energy
Hydrogen
Hydrexia
Hydrogen
Hydrogenics
Hydrogen
McPhy Energy
Aqueous Hybrid Ion Aquion Energy
Lithium-ion
ABB
Lithium-ion
China BAK Storage
Lithium-ion
Envia Systems
Lithium-ion
Tesla Motors
Batteries
ElectrocheLiquid metal
mical energy
battery
Ambri
Zinc Hybrid
Cathode
Technology
Eos Energy Storage
Ultracapacitors
Ioxus
CAES
Airlight energy
CAES
LightSail Energy
Mechanical energy
LAES
Highview Power
Flywheel
Beacon Power Corporation
Thermal energy
PHES
Isentropic
Efficiency
4energy
Bridgelux
Cooltech Applications
NovaLed
Performance efficiency
Nualight
Phoebus Energy
Phononic
SorTech
Va-Q-tec
Digital Lumens
Enlighted
FirstFuel
Gridpoint
iControl Networks
Ijenko
Monitoring and management
Nest
Opower
Qualisteo
Tendril
Wattio
USA
Canada
France
Australia
Canada
France
USA
Switzerland
China
USA
USA
USA
USA
USA
Switzerland
USA
UK
USA
UK
UK
USA
France
Germany
Ireland
Israel
USA
Germany
Germany
USA
USA
USA
USA
USA
France
USA
USA
France
USA
Spain
Annex | 161
Building materials
Next step living
Project Frog
SageGlass
Sefaira
Serious Energy
Infrastructure
AutoGrid
Cisco Systems
Enbala
Gridco Systems
Intel
Grid management
Itron
On-Ramp Wireless
Schneider Electric
Space-Time insight
Trilliant
Amantys
T&D grids
Transphorm
Wide Technology portfolio
Wind, Solar Photovoltaic, CSP, Hydroelectric,
Biomass
Acciona
Nuclear, Wind, Solar, Hydrogen storage
Areva
Wind, Solar, Nuclear
NextEra Energy resources
Renewable energy, Fossil fuel, Smart grids,
Hydrogen Storage
Siemens
Si-PV, Thin-film, Hydrogen storage
The Linde Group
USA
USA
USA
UK
USA
USA
USA
Canada
USA
USA
USA
USA
France
USA
USA
UK
USA
Spain
France
USA
Germany
Germany
Annex | 162
References
[1] “World Energy Assessment. Energy and the challenge of sustainability”, United Nations and World
Energy Council - 2000
[2] “World Energy Outlook 2013”, IEA - 2013
[3] Website, NOAA Earth System Research Laboratory – Global monitoring division
[4] “Decreasing dependency on fossil fuels.The role of EU public banks in energy financing in Central
Europe and Eastern Europe”, CEE and Bankwatch network –April 2013
[5] Ley 24/2013 Art. 6
[6] “El sistema eléctrico español 2013”, REE – April 2014
[7] “Listado de comercializadores de Referencia con la información relativa al Bono Social”, CNMC –
December 2014
[8] “The World Energy Trilemma. Time to get real – the agenda for change”, World Energy Council - 2013
[9] “Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations framework convention on climate change”, United Nations - 1998
[10] “Doha amendment to the Kyoto Protocol”, United Nations
[11] The 2020 climate and energy package, European Commission website
[12] Press release: “Cinco claves para entender el déficit de tarifa de las eléctricas”, La VanguardiaDecember 2013
[13] Press release: “Con un simple rumor el Gobierno ha conseguido frenar el autoconsumo eléctrico”, El
Confidencial – February 2015
[14] “Climate Change 2013: The Physical Science Basis. Chapter 2: Observations: Atmosphere and
Surface”, Hartmann et al. - 2013
[15] “World Energy Outlook 2013”, IEA - 2013
[16] “Pobreza Energética en España: análisis de tendencias”, Asociación de Ciencias Ambientales - 2014
[17] “World Energy Outlook 2013”, IEA - 2013
[18] Factiva
[19] “Registration of Crude Oil Imports and deliveries in the European Union (EU27)”, European
Commission - 2013
References | 163
[20] “Registration of Crude Oil Imports and deliveries in the European Union (EU27)”, European
Commission - 2013
[21] 2020 Goal Progress in P&G corporate website
[22]“Wind in power, 2013 European statistics”, EWEA – February 2014
[23] “Global trends in clean energy investment”, Bloomberg – April 2013
[24]“Global trends in clean energy investment”, Bloomberg – April 2013
[25]“Global trends in clean energy investment”, Bloomberg – April 2013
[26] Global Cleantech 100: www.cleantech.com/indexes/global-cleantech-100
[27]“Renewable energy technologies: cost analysis series, Solar Photovoltaics”, IRENA – June 2012
[28] Press release: “EU imposes definitive measures on Chinese solar panels, confirms undertaking with
Chinese solar exporters”, European Commission – December 2013
[29] “Wind in power, 2013 European statistics”, EWEA – February 2014
[30]“World Energy Outlook 2013”, IEA - 2013
[31] Carbon Capture and Storage section in IEA´s webpage
[32] Press release: “A coal plant that buries its greenhouse gases”, MIT Technology review – December
2014
[33] World Nuclear Association webpage: www.world-nuclear.org
[34] Lockheed Martin corporate webpage: www.lockheedmartin.com
[35] “Electricity Storage. Technology Brief”, IRENA – April 2012
[36] “US Energy Storage Technology Outlook”, Energy Storage Update - 2015
[37] Tesla Motors corporate webpage: www.teslamotors.com
[38] “US Energy Storage Technology Outlook”, Energy Storage Update - 2015
[39] “Electricity Storage. Technology Brief”, IRENA – April 2012
[40] Press release: “Irizar presenta su primer autobús eléctrico”, Foro Coches Electricos – July 2014
[41] Press release: “All aboard China´s new Supercapacitor tram”, Oil price – July 2014
[42] Compressed Air Energy Storage (CAES), Energy Storage Association
[43] Flywheels, Energy Storage Association
[44] Pumped Heat Electrical Storage (PHES), Energy Storage Association
[45] Isentropic corporate webpage: www.isentropic.co.uk
References | 164
[46] Press release: “A reversible heat-pump promises a cheap way to store renewable energy on the grid”,
The Economist – June 2014
[47] “Informe de innovación 2011-2013”, Iberdrola - 2013
[48] CIGRE webpage: www.cigre.org
[49] “Global Energy Transitions”, WEC & A.T. Kearney – October 2014
[50] “Wind in power, 2013 European statistics”, EWEA – February 2014
[51] “Global Market Outlook for Photovoltaics 2014-2018”, EPIA - 2014
[52] “Offshore Wind Turbines and Foundations – Global Market Size, Market Share, Regulations and Key
Country Analysis to 2020”, GlobalData - 2014
[53] “Grid Energy Storage”, U.S. Department of Energy – December 2013
[54] Press release: “La venta de coches eléctricos se doble en Europa”, El País – July 2014
[55] “Keynote at AltCar Expo: 100% Electric Transportation and 100% Solar by 2030”, Tony Seba –
October 2014
[56] “El sistema eléctrico español. Avance del informe”, REE – December 2014
[57] “Planificación de los sectores de electricidad y gas 2012-2020”, MINETUR - July 2011
[58] “Informe marco sobre la demanda de energía eléctrica y gas natural, y su cobertura. Horizonte 20132017”, CNMC – March 2014
[59] “Evaluating the effect of intermittent renewables on the wholesale electricity market in Germany”,
Andrew Adelfio – April 2014
[60] Factor utilización ciclos combinados, estadísticas Sedigas – November 2014
[61] Press release: “Industria reactiva el plan de hibernación de los ciclos combinados tras un año de
parón”, El Confidencial – July 2014
[62] E.ON corporate website, Press releases – 30 Novemeber 2014
[63] “El sistema eléctrico español. Avance del informe”, REE – December 2014
[64] “El sistema eléctrico español. Avance del informe”, REE – December 2014
[65] “Offshore Wind Turbines and Foundations – Global Market Size, Market Share, Regulations and Key
Country Analysis to 2020”, GlobalData - 2014
[66] “Levelized cost of electricity renewable energy technologies”, Fraunhofer ISE – November 2013
[67] “UK Renewable Energy Roadmap”, DECC – July 2011
[68] “UK Renewable Energy Roadmap Update 2013”, DECC – November 2013
[69] Press release: “UK could miss 2020 offshore target”, Wind Power Offshore – December 2013
References | 165
[70] Ofgem website: www.ofgem.gov.uk
[71] Press release: “RWE pull out Galloper wind farm scheme”, BBC – October 2014
[72] Press release: “Offshore wind farms may be scrapped due to budget cap, Scottish Power warns”, The
Telegraph – October 2014
th
[73] Press release: “DECC boosts offshore CfDs”, Renews – 28 January 2015
[74] “CfD Auction Allocation Round One – a breakdown of the outcome by technology, year and clearing
th
price”, DECC – February 26 2015
[75] Press release: “Offshore wind farms may be scrapped due to budget cap, Scottish Power warns”, The
Telegraph – October 2014
[76] “The European offshore wind industry. Key trend and statistics 2014”, EWEA - January 2015
[77] "Deep Water. The next step for offshore wind energy", EWEA - July 2013
[78] “Installation of suction caissons for Offshore Wind Turbines”, Statoil – April 2014
[79] "Deep Water. The next step for offshore wind energy", EWEA - July 2013
[80] “Wind in our Sails”, EWEA - 2011
[81] “Offshore Wind Transmission Study, Final Report”, ESS Group, Inc – September 2014
[82] “Offshore Wind Market and Economic Analysis. 2014 Annual Market Assessment”, U.S. Department
of Energy – August 2014
[83] “Wind in our Sails”, EWEA - 2011
[84] “The European offshore wind industry. Key trend and statistics 2014”, EWEA - January 2015
[85] A.T. Kearney experience
[86] “Future renewable energy costs: offshore wind”, BVG associates - 2014
[87] Find original CNAE activities in www.cnae.com.es/lista-actividades.php
[88] “Censo de Población y Viviendas 2011. Datos detallados”, INE – December 2013
[89] “Distribución de la renta en España: Desigualdad, cambios estructurales y ciclos”, Consejo
económico y social España – March 2013
[90] “Customer Engagement with the Energy Market – Tracking Survey 2013”, Ofgem – June 2013
[91] Average annual domestic standard electricity bills, DECC – Updated October 2014
[92] A.T. Kearney experience
References | 166