Roots and Remedies of the Welsh Growth Collapse
Transcription
Roots and Remedies of the Welsh Growth Collapse
Offa’s Gap Roots and Remedies of the Welsh Growth Collapse A Discussion Paper Plaid Cymru’s Economic Commission Offa’s Gap Page 2 You can contact the Commission: By email: [email protected] By post: The Economic Commission, Plaid Cymru. Anson Court, Atlantic Wharf, Cardiff. CF10 4AL By phone: 029 2047 2272 www.plaidcymru.org/economy Offa’s Gap Page Offa’s Gap Roots and Remedies of the Welsh Growth Collapse A Discussion Paper Plaid Cymru’s Economic Commission 3 Offa’s Gap Page 4 Introduction The Welsh economy is in crisis. The collapse in its economic output since 2007 ran in parallel with the Great Recession. But its problems run much deeper. The Welsh economy has been growing slower relative to its historic trend growth and that of the UK economy for the last two decades. While the inherited problems of the Welsh economy, those associated with its industrial legacy, are well understood, this paper seeks to ask the simple question: what made a bad situation worse? The combination of our economic history and our recent experience means Wales faces a dual developmental problem. As an economy and a society that was at the vanguard of the Industrial Revolution Wales displays many of the social and environmental scars that are the by-products of rapid economic growth based largely on natural resource-based industries. Wales, in common with most of the northern hemisphere, is in many ways having to confront the problems and challenges of uneconomic growth or over-development. Overcoming the problems associated with this will be very much the focus of our sister Commission on Sustainable Communities. Wales’ other developmental problem flows from the uneven nature of development itself, both historically and geographically. Wales, once a powerhouse of economic progress, now finds itself at the bottom of the UK’s and, increasingly, the EU’s prosperity league tables. We are well on the way to becoming the most under-developed land in the advanced post-industrial world. The first step in solving any problem is establishing its nature and its scale. This means having some measure that allows us to compare performance over time and contrast with the experience of other countries. In this report we use regional output as measured by Gross Domestic Product (GDP) historically and more recently by Gross Value Added or GVA (which was previously known as GDP at basic prices). This is not a perfect metric for measuring social and economic welfare for reasons that are now well understood. GVA does not acknowledge the effects on the prosperity of citizens of a given country of having an unequal distribution of income or allowing the transfer of resources to foreign individuals through exports or the profits of multinational firms. GVA measures some bad things, e.g. clean up costs from a pollution incident, as positives, and fails to measure other bad things, e.g. the original pollution incident, as costs. The relationship between happiness and GVA per capita, though by some measures positive, is a good deal more complex than the general obsession with economic growth would suggest. Offa’s Gap Page 5 Despite its imperfections, however, GVA remains the single most useful indicator in seeking to evaluate economic performance – though other broader indices, like the Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare, are undoubtedly better tools for measuring genuine social and economic wellbeing. In the specific context of Wales, where we are seeking to understand the dynamics of underdevelopment, GVA remains a key benchmark in the same way that poverty for an individual is measured primarily in terms of income. Particularly because of its transparency and uniformity as a measure of economic activity, GVA is also the best available method we have for comparing economic performance over time and across geographies. Our starting point in this Commission is the belief that raising Welsh GVA per capita has to be a key strategic goal of Welsh economic policy – and that the abandonment of an explicit target by the Welsh Government, or the shift to a measure that includes central government transfers, is an acceptance of failure Wales can ill afford. Our focus in this report is on diagnostics: What is wrong with the Welsh economy, what are the symptoms, what is the syndrome, what is the underlying cause? The important thing, of course, is to cure the problem. Growth therapeutics will become the focus of the Commission over the course of the next four years. With the launch of this report we are inviting everyone in Wales to participate in this essential process of discovering together the ideas and strategies that will offer our country a better economic future. There can be no monopoly on good ideas in this regard. Indeed only by pooling our intelligence can we hope to begin the task of charting a different course. Dr Eurfyl ap Gwilym Adam Price Co-Chairs - Plaid Cymru’s Economic Commission Cardiff, July 2012 Offa’s Gap Page 6 Offa’s Gap: the Welsh growth crisis Offa’s Dyke, that mound of earth still visible and built by an eighth century Saxon King, remains as a metaphorical border between England and Wales. But in the late 20th century a new dividing line came to be associated with the two countries: a gap in relative prosperity. Welsh GVA per capita1 is currently just above 73% of the UK average, and Wales lies at the bottom of the UK prosperity league table (12th out of 12 UK Standard Regions). This new chasm in economic realities we call “Offa’s Gap”. In some sense this new divide represents a long historic unwinding from a high-point when Welsh coal powered and Welsh slate roofed the world. The economic historian Nick Crafts has estimated that Welsh income per head in 1891 was 96.2% of the UK average.2 Since then Wales has experienced a century of relative decline, in particular in the inter-war period as coal was supplanted by oil as the major fuel of the modern economy 100 95 GDP at Factor Cost GDP at Basic Prices 90 85 80 2009 2007 2005 2003 2001 1999 1997 1995 1993 1991 1989 1987 1985 1983 1981 1979 1977 1975 1973 1971 1955 1931 1911 70 1891 75 1871 as a % of UK average (excluding Continental Shelf) Welsh GDP per capita, 1871-2010 Source: 1871-1911 (Crafts, 2005); 1954-2009, CSO/ONS Figure 1: Post-war Recovery and Recent Decline Yet, as we see from Figure 1, by 1971 the Welsh economy, which had benefitted from some form of regional policy designed to diversify its economic base from the 1930s on, had recovered much of its relative position. Excluding the exceptional years 1974, 1980/81 and 1985, which were all to some extent marred by the impact of major industrial disputes in the staple coal and steel industries, the Residence-based GVA at current basic prices Nicholas Crafts, 2005. "Regional GDP in Britain, 1871-1911: Some Estimates," Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Scottish Economic Society, vol. 52(1), pages 54-64, 02. 1 2 Offa’s Gap Page 7 Welsh economy for almost twenty years, between 1971 and 1988, remained in the 85%-90% range relative to UK GDP per capita. Indeed in the latter half of the 1980s Welsh GDP growth was the highest of all UK regions (see Figure 2). 12 Regional Growth, real GDP per head 10 8 4 2 -4 1990 1989 1988 1987 Lowest Regional Growth Highest Regional Growth Wales -6 -8 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 1979 1978 1977 1976 1975 1974 -2 1973 0 1972 % change 6 Source: ONS Figure 2: the 1980s Resurgence During the 1980s the Welsh Development Agency, formed in 1977, achieved considerable success in attracting Foreign Direct Investment, with Wales consistently out-performing other parts of the UK. In July 1992 the Welsh unemployment rate fell below the UK average for the first time in living memory, a symbolically important result that was surpassed a year later when Welsh unemployment fell below that of the South East of England. By the mid-1990s most economic forecasters predicted a decade of superior economic growth with Wales continuing to narrow the gap with the rest of the UK.3 Wales’ actual economic performance since then has been dismal. Welsh GVA per capita growth was significantly below that of the UK as a whole in all but two of the years between 1990 and 20094. As can be seen from Figure 3 the general trend of Welsh growth tended to follow that of the UK economy until a marked growth deceleration experienced between 1996 and 1999 that was responsible for a particularly pronounced deterioration in relative Welsh prosperity. It’s since this mid-90s turning point – a modern ‘growth climacteric’ - that Offa’s Gap has opened up. 3 Alden, J. (1996), “The transfer from a problem to a powerful region”, in: J. Alden and P. Boland, Regional Development Strategies: A European Perspective, Kingsley/Regional Studies Association. 4 using the 1989-2009 continuous record Offa’s Gap Page 8 Real GVA Growth, 1990-2009 5 4 % annual change 3 2 1 UK 0 Wales -1 -2 -3 -4 Source: ONS, author's calculations Figure 3: The 90s’ Growth Collapse Figure 4 shows the discrepancy in growth rates between Wales and the UK from 1972 to 2009. While the 1970s and 1980s were characterized by volatility in relative performance, the downswings were generally matched by periods of resurgence. Since 1996, however, the Welsh economy has been in a period of almost continuous relative decline. Welsh/UK Growth Rate Differential, 1972-2010 6 4 -4 -6 -8 Figure 4: A decade and a half of decline Source: ONS, author's calculations 2010 2008 2006 2004 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 -2 1976 0 1974 2 2002 GDP at factor cost GDP at basic prices 1972 Welsh Nominal Growth Rate - UK Nominal Growth Rate 8 Offa’s Gap Page 9 The compounded average growth rate (CAGR) for Welsh GDP per capita between 1971 and 1990, 1.96%, was almost identical to the UK rate of 1.99%. Over the succeeding two decades, however, a gap has opened up with Welsh income per capita growing at a rate of just 1.25% compared with 1.87% for the UK as a whole. In cumulative terms this 0.6% gap meant that while the Welsh economy pretty much matched the UK economy pound for pound with a real terms increase income of 46% versus the UK’s 47% between 1971 and 1990, over the succeeding period, 1991-2010, Welsh income growth was just 27% compared with the 42% registered by the UK as a whole. The cost of this modern Offa’s Gap to every person in Wales– the amount of additional income per capita lost by the failure to keep up with the UK economy – amounts to £1850 a year. A key fact to grasp from this analysis is that Welsh economic growth over the last two decades is lower not just in geographic terms, relative to the rest of the UK, but also historically, when compared to our own past economic performance. Where previously the performance of the Welsh economy had generally followed the growth trajectory of the UK economy, these paths diverged markedly from the late 90s onwards. This is best captured by Figure 5 that shows the rolling average of economic growth for the two economies over the preceding five years. Up until 1992 the smoothed growth patterns of the Welsh economy and the UK economy are almost perfectly correlated (with a coefficient of 96%), but this falls by a quarter in the following years. From 1996 the Welsh economy has been on a very different track. 6 Real GVA Growth, Five-year Rolling Average 5 Wales 5yr average 4 % 3 2 1 0 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 ‐1 ‐2 Figure 5: The Great Divergence Source: ONS, author's calculations 2005 2010 Offa’s Gap Page 10 One of the most common explanations for this deterioration in Wales’ relative economic fortunes is the boom in financial services and other high value-added activity concentrated primarily in London. Welsh GVA per capita did fall in relation to London GVA per capita from 53.73% in 1989 to 43.4% two decades later. But it also fell compared to the Rest of the UK (excluding London and Wales) from 88.46% to 79.91% in 2009. In actual fact the London effect is only responsible for a little over a third of the 10-point decline in Welsh GVA per capita relative to the UK. Most of the decline in Welsh economic growth is explained by its failure to keep pace with the UK as a whole not London in particular. If Wales had achieved the same growth rate as the mostly post-industrial extra-London UK economy then GVA per capita in 2009 would be 80.7%, not, as it turned out, 74.3% of the UK average. Blaming the rise of the City of London directly for all the woes of the Welsh economy would appear to be misplaced – though its indirect influence on wider UK policy may have played a bigger role. Placing the collapse in the Welsh growth rate in some sort of historical perspective is hampered by the lack of GDP data before the mid-50s. With this in mind economic historians Frank Geary and Tom Stark have developed historical GDP estimates stretching back to 1901.5 By their estimate, Welsh GDP as a share of the overall UK figure has fallen as much over the period 1991-2007 as it had done in the previous 60 years. In relative terms, as measured by economic output at least, the last twenty years is the worst period in Welsh economic history for which data exists. The inter-war period and its aftermath, which through collective memory of mass unemployment and emigration looms large in the Welsh imagination, saw a much smaller decline in Wales’ relative position. 5 Frank Geary and Tom Stark (2011), Estimates of Regional GDP in the United Kingdom, unpublished Offa’s Gap Page 11 Wales' Share of UK GDP, 1901-2007 4.8 % share of UK GDP 4.6 4.4 4.2 4 3.8 3.6 3.4 1901 1911 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 Source: Geary and Stark (2011) 1981 1991 2001 Figure 6: The Arc of Decline The decline in relative Welsh prosperity is not a purely domestic phenomenon limited to our decline in relation to the Rest of the UK. Wales has also undergone a rapid phase of deterioration in its economic ranking internationally. Figure 7 shows Welsh per capita GDP relative to the EU average over the fifteen year period to 2009. The 13-point slide in the Welsh position relative to the EU is considerably worse than its 5-point slide relative to the UK in the same time period. Within the entire European Union, only the Walloon region of Belgium equalled Wales’ rate of relative decline. The UK as a whole by contrast dropped just two points relative to the EU-27 over the same period – down from 114% to 112%. Offa’s Gap Page 12 Welsh GDP per capita as % of EU-27 average PPS per inhabitant as % of the EU average 95 93 91 89 87 85 83 81 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 79 Source: Eurostat Figure 7: The Sick Man of Europe Across the European Union a strong tendency towards economic convergence can be observed with the poorest regions in general growing much faster and the richer regions growing more slowly. Figure 8 illustrates this trend by mapping NUTS 1 regions’ starting income per capita in 1995 (measured on a logarithmic scale) against their compounded nominal growth over the fourteen years to 2009. The downward slope of the trend-line shows quite a strong negative relationship between starting income and growth rates i.e. it confirms the convergence effect. The Scottish economy’s growth rate of 3.1% over this period is almost exactly as predicted by its level of income given the simple convergence equation. Some regions buck the trend, however. London is among those already rich regions that are getting even richer in relative terms. Wales is in the least favourable quadrant of poorer than average regions that are getting even poorer in relative terms. Indeed, Wales’ position over this time period as having the worst economic growth of any poorer than average region means it can be legitimately described as the worst performing economic region in the whole of the EU. Offa’s Gap Page 13 Compound Annual GVA growth rate, 1995-2009 (current prcies, PPP per inahbitant) 9.0% 8.0% 7.0% 6.0% 5.0% 4.0% 3.0% 2.0% R² = 0.49745 1.0% 0.0% 8.0 8.5 9.0 9.5 10.0 10.5 11.0 Ln (GVA, PPP per inhabitant), 1995 Figure 8: Wrong Side of the Tracks Source: Eurostat, author’s calculations It hasn’t always been this way. For most of the 20th century Welsh economic growth has generally followed that of the advanced industrialised world. It is only in the last fifteen years or so that Offa’s Gap has opened up, not just with the rest of the Island of Britain but more worryingly still, increasingly with the rest of the world. Wales’ current trend rate of growth in real GDP per capita of between 1.2 and 1.5% is well below the roughly 2.0% long-run growth rate of the UK and most high-income countries. Figure 9 extrapolates the effect of this divergence on income per capita from now until midcentury using long-term projections published by PriceWaterhouseCoopers.6 Projections are merely that: predictions based on current and recent performance. They are by no means inevitable. But what we can say is that the Welsh economy, which now occupies a position towards the lower end among the advanced economies, will likely be overtaken by Russia, Mexico, Turkey and Argentina before midcentury on current trends and cease to be classed as a high-income country, when considered independently, within about twenty years. 6 John Hawksworth and Gordon Cookson, The World in 2050, PwC, 2011 Offa’s Gap Page 14 Figure 9: The Welsh economy in 2050 In trying to understand the underlying reasons for the Welsh Growth Collapse we are severely hampered by the lack of reliable and comprehensive data. Analysing GDP with reference to its component parts is simply not possible in many cases as time series data in a sufficiently disaggregated form is simply not available. The expenditure-based formula for GDP: Y= C (private consumption expenditure) + I (private investment expenditure) + G (Government consumption and investment expenditure) + X-M (Exports – Imports) Offa’s Gap Page 15 is difficult to reproduce for Welsh GDP as we lack any official figures for international trade in services, for investment (despite the publication of regional gross fixed capital formation statistics being a legal requirement) and intra-regional trade in goods and services within the UK. We do, however, have figures for gross fixed capital formation for the critical period 1996-2000 and they give us some insight to the fall in the economic growth rate during that five year period. Chart 1: Welsh GDP (expenditure method) Identifiable Government expenditure Non-identifiable Government expenditure (within Wales) Consumer expenditure Private gross fixed capital formation Net foreign goods exports Net foreign services exports GDP Residual - Net exports of goods and services to rest of the UK £million, current prices 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 8196 8293 8613 8938 9521 880 18562 850 18883 920 19320 855 19937 995 20,137 4671 (e) 5305 (e) 6062 5674 5001 2513 2155 1485 805 1335 -1001 (e) -956 (e) -1082 (e) -1286 (e) -1365 (e) 27518 28672 29787 30736 31898 -6303 -5858 -5531 -4187 -3726 Source: UK Treasury PESA annual report, various years; Regional Trends, various years; ONS statistics on subnational GFCF, 2003; HMRC Regional Trade Statistics; author’s calculations What is clear from the figures is that the relative decline in Welsh growth during this period was driven by problems in the business sector. Government expenditure (identifiable and non-identifiable expenditure within Wales on government services) increased by about £1.5 billion in nominal terms over the period, though at a slightly slower rate than the UK as a whole probably due to the effects of Barnett Convergence. Welsh household consumption also declined relative to the UK as a whole during this period. There may have been some effect from the fact that house prices in Wales, and the potential for equity release which drove some of the consumption boom during this period, grew at a slower rate relative to the south east of England. However, the impact of this slower growth is dwarfed by the fall of £1.7 billion in net exports (extra UK) between 1996 and 1999. This fall in goods exports amounts to 6% of Welsh GDP, which is the same amount by which Welsh GDP fell relative to the rest of the UK during the latter half of the 90s. Offa’s Gap Page 16 This snapshot – and it must be stressed that the figures contained here can only be indicative – does tend to confirm the importance of the export base as a key driver of economic development. The central role of those industries producing goods and services for markets outside the region to understanding the growth process was first proposed by the American economists Charles Tiebout and Douglass North in the 1950s. The Hungarian-born Cambridge economist, Nicholas Kaldor, who was to become the architect of British regional policy under the Wilson Labour governments, merged this idea with Gunnar Myrdal’s concept of “cumulative causation”. This model of regional growth stressed not just the short-run demand stimulus of an increase in exports but also the more long-term virtuous circle of increasing returns to scale, and the productivity gains resulting from greater output (the socalled Verdoorn effect). The British economist A.P. Thirlwall also proposed a regional version of his balance of payments constraint, which essentially meant that a region’s long run rate of growth depended on the ratio between its growth in exports and the income elasticity of its imports. A region with sluggish exports and a tendency to import high income elasticity manufactured goods or services would experience lower economic growth. There is evidence for a collapse in productivity in the late 90s that would be consistent with the Verdoorn effect. Labour productivity in Wales was relatively high and grew relatively fast during the 1980s and early 1990s. When measured by gross output per employee Wales had the highest productivity in the UK between 1984 and 1996.7 When measured by gross value added per employee, Welsh labour productivity was lower (because of the effects of a higher than average level of intermediate outputs) but still remained above the UK average between 1987 and 1996. Figure 10 shows figures for productivity growth over the period 1979-1998 which on both measures of labour productivity show a stronger than average performance between 1979 and 1994. However, figures from this Welsh Government study by the respected Scottish economist Richard Harris using detailed and previously unavailable statistics from the most comprehensive dataset available to researchers, the Annual Respondents Database, show a precipitous decline in the 1994-98 period. Harris’ figures suggest an average annual reduction in gross value added in manufacturing of some 18.5%, and a dramatic reversal of Wales’ relative position, from approximately 40% above the UK average to 20% below in just five years. R. Harris, (2006), Labour Productivity Growth in Wales 1990-1998: Evidence Based on the Annual Respondents Database: Department of Economics and Finance, University of Durham (mimeo). 7 Percentage change per annum Offa’s Gap Page 17 10 5 GVA per worker, Wales 0 ‐5 1974‐79 1979‐84 1984‐89 1989‐94 1994‐98 GVA per worker, UK ‐10 Gross output per worker, Wales ‐15 Gross output per worker, UK ‐20 Source: Harris (2006) Figure 10: Real productivity growth in manufacturing Published datasets provide a less dramatic picture of a standstill in real Welsh GVA per job in manufacturing rather than the massive fall suggested in Harris’ work, together with a steady decline relative to the rest of the UK. But there are other indications of a significant shock to the business sector during this period. The late 90s Welsh growth climacteric coincided with a precipitous decline in Welsh business profitability. Gross Operating Surplus – which includes income not derived from wages – had a higher share in Welsh GVA than the UK as a whole at the beginning of the 1990s but collapsed in the middle of the decade and is now 5% lower than for the UK. Gross Operating Surplus 44.00% 42.00% % GVA 40.00% 38.00% Wales UK 36.00% 34.00% 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 32.00% Figure 11: The Welsh Profits Crisis Source: ONS Offa’s Gap Page 18 Wales – for these purposes, an “economic region” not a nation-state – is more vulnerable to the effects of exports on its economic growth than the UK as a whole. This follows from the fact that the Welsh economy is more “open” i.e. the share of exports and imports (including those to the rest of the United Kingdom) are much larger than that of the UK, whose domestic economy is relatively more important. Allied to this is the fact that the Welsh Government has none of the policy levers available to a national government – currency depreciation, fiscal or monetary stimulus – in responding to an exogenous shock. Without accompanying transfer payments the only short-term response possible is a reduction in income levels. There is strong evidence suggesting the Welsh economy suffered a major economic shock in the latter half of the 90s, the effects of which were to be long-lasting. The roots of this shock lie to some extent in the policy of non-intervention in the currency market that led to what some commentators regarded as an over-valuation in the pound. Figure 12 shows the exchange rate of the Pound against the Euro, and prior to its introduction the basket of European currencies that made up the European Currency Unit. The pound appreciated by around 25% for a period of 11 years between 1996 and the onset of the financial crisis.8 This period of over-valuation – fuelled by the strong performance of the City of London in the export of financial services and in the attraction of inflows of capital and invisible earnings – led to a deteriorating trade balance in goods, and a haemorrhaging of jobs in the manufacturing sector. It was Wales’ particular misfortune that this period of over-valuation proved even more painful than a similar period of over-valuation in the early 1980s as it coincided with the entry into first the European Economic Area and then the EU of low-wage but relatively high-skilled former Communist countries in Central and Eastern Europe. 8 It should be noted that this pattern of appreciation was specific to the Euro-zone are. The pound began to appreciate much later against the dollar in the period 2002-2007. Offa’s Gap Page 1.000000 Period of Appreciation 0.900000 0.800000 Pounds per Euro/ECU 19 0.700000 0.600000 0.500000 0.400000 0.300000 0.200000 0.100000 1990M01 1990M10 1991M07 1992M04 1993M01 1993M10 1994M07 1995M04 1996M01 1996M10 1997M07 1998M04 1999M01 1999M10 2000M07 2001M04 2002M01 2002M10 2003M07 2004M04 2005M01 2005M10 2006M07 2007M04 2008M01 2008M10 2009M07 2010M04 2011M01 0.000000 Figure 12: Sterling’s Costly Decade Source: Eurostat Against this backdrop the recovery in Welsh manufactured exports post 1999 is impressive. Figure 13 shows a 102.6% increase in total exports, at current prices, over the period 1996-2010. 2011Q2 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 14000000 13000000 12000000 11000000 10000000 9000000 8000000 7000000 6000000 5000000 4000000 1996 '000s (pounds sterling, current prices) Total Welsh Exports in Goods Source: HMRC Figure 13: Welsh Exports Rebound Wales’ share of total UK exports (excluding the 15% of total UK exports for which no geographic designation is possible) has risen from 4.09% in 1996 to 5.52% by the second quarter of 2011. This compares with Wales’ resident population share of 4.83 %. Offa’s Gap Page 20 6.00% 5.50% 5.00% 4.50% 2011Q2 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 4.00% 1996 % of UK Total (excluding nonidentifiable) Welsh Exports as a share of Total UK Exports (Goods) Source: HMRC Figure 14: Wales, Export Leader The success of the Welsh export sector is demonstrated in Figure 15 that shows the index of goods exported over the last fifteen years. Wales over this period has powered ahead, outstripping export growth in the rest of the UK and particularly in comparable economic regions like Scotland whose export volumes have been stagnant. Index of Goods Exported 230 Index, 1996=100 210 190 170 Wales 150 UK 130 Scotland 110 90 70 Source: HMRC Figure 15: Wales, Export Champion A slightly less positive picture emerges when we examine the composition of Welsh exports. Since 1996 Welsh exports have become considerably less diversified. In 1996 seven sectors registered a share of 5% of total exports or above. By 2010 this had fallen to just three, with two sectors, petroleum 0% 00 Live Animals Other Than Animals Of Division 03 01 Meat & Meat Preparations 02 Dairy Products & Birds Eggs 03 Fish,Crustaceans,Molluscs & Aq.Inverts & Preps Thereof 04 Cereals & Cereal Preparations 05 Vegetables & Fruit 06 Sugar, Sugar Preparations & Honey 07 Coffee, Tea, Cocoa, Spices & Manufactures Thereof 08 Feeding Stuff For Animals (Not Inc.Unmilled Cereals) 09 Miscellaneous Edible Products & Preparations 11 Beverages 12 Tobacco & Tobacco Manufactures 21 Hides, Skins & Furskins, Raw 22 Oil Seeds & Oleaginous Fruits 23 Crude Rubber (Including Synthetic & Reclaimed) 24 Cork & Wood 25 Pulp & Waste Paper 26 Textile Fibres Not Manufactured & Their Waste Etc 27 Crude Fertilizers & Crude Minerals (Exc Fuels Etc) 28 Metalliferous Ores & Metal Scrap 29 Crude Animal & Vegetable Materials N.E.S. 32 Coal, Coke & Briquettes 33 Petroleum, Petroleum Products & Related Materials 34 Gas, Natural & Manufactured 35 Electric Current 41 Animal Oils & Fats 42 Fixed Vegetable Fats & Oils, Crude,Refined,Fractionated 43 Animal Or Vegetable Fats & Oils, Processed, & Waxes 51 Organic Chemicals 52 Inorganic Chemicals 53 Dyeing, Tanning & Colouring Materials 54 Medicinal & Pharmaceutical Products 55 Essential Oils & Perfume Materials; Toilet Preps Etc 56 Fertilizers (Other Than Those Of Group 272) 57 Plastics In Primary Forms 58 Plastics In Non-Primary Forms 59 Chemical Materials & Products N.E.S. 61 Leather, Leather Manufactures N.E.S & Dressed Furskins 62 Rubber Manufactures N.E.S. 63 Cork & Wood Manufactures (Excluding Furniture) 64 Paper, Paperboard & Manufactures Thereof 65 Textile Yarn, Fabrics, Made Up Articles Etc 66 Non-Metallic Mineral Manufactures N.E.S. 67 Iron & Steel 68 Non-Ferrous Metals 69 Manufactures Of Metal N.E.S. 71 Power Generating Machinery & Equipment 72 Machinery Specialized For Particular Industries 73 Metalworking Machinery 74 General Industrial Machinery & Eqp. & Machine Pt.N.E.S. 75 Office Machines & Adp Machines 76 Telecomms & Sound Recording & Reproducing App. & Eqp. 77 Ele Machinery, App & Appliances & Ele Pt Thereof N.E.S. 78 Road Vehicles (Including Air Cushion Vehicles) 79 Other Transport Equipment 81 P/Fab Buildings;Sanit.,Plumbing,Heating &Lighting Fixt. 82 Furniture & Parts Thereof; Bedding, Mattresses Etc 83 Travel Goods, Handbags & Similar Containers 84 Articles Of Apparel & Clothing Accessories 85 Footwear 87 Professional, Scientific & Controlling Ins & App N.E.S. 88 Photographic & Optical Goods, N.E.S.; Watches & Clocks 89 Miscellaneous Manufactured Articles N.E.S. 9 Commodities not classified elsewhere; Offa’s Gap Page Source: HMRC Figure 16: Welsh Good Exports by Sector, 1996 21 products, and power generating machinery and equipment, responsible for almost half (47%) of total Welsh exports (see figures 16, 17 and 18). 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 00 Live Animals Other Than Animals Of Division 03 01 Meat & Meat Preparations 02 Dairy Products & Birds Eggs 03 Fish,Crustaceans,Molluscs & Aq.Inverts & Preps Thereof 04 Cereals & Cereal Preparations 05 Vegetables & Fruit 06 Sugar, Sugar Preparations & Honey 07 Coffee, Tea, Cocoa, Spices & Manufactures Thereof 08 Feeding Stuff For Animals (Not Inc.Unmilled Cereals) 09 Miscellaneous Edible Products & Preparations 11 Beverages 12 Tobacco & Tobacco Manufactures 21 Hides, Skins & Furskins, Raw 22 Oil Seeds & Oleaginous Fruits 23 Crude Rubber (Including Synthetic & Reclaimed) 24 Cork & Wood 25 Pulp & Waste Paper 26 Textile Fibres Not Manufactured & Their Waste Etc 27 Crude Fertilizers & Crude Minerals (Exc Fuels Etc) 28 Metalliferous Ores & Metal Scrap 29 Crude Animal & Vegetable Materials N.E.S. 32 Coal, Coke & Briquettes 33 Petroleum, Petroleum Products & Related Materials 34 Gas, Natural & Manufactured 35 Electric Current 41 Animal Oils & Fats 42 Fixed Vegetable Fats & Oils, Crude,Refined,Fractionated 43 Animal Or Vegetable Fats & Oils, Processed, & Waxes 51 Organic Chemicals 52 Inorganic Chemicals 53 Dyeing, Tanning & Colouring Materials 54 Medicinal & Pharmaceutical Products 55 Essential Oils & Perfume Materials; Toilet Preps Etc 56 Fertilizers (Other Than Those Of Group 272) 57 Plastics In Primary Forms 58 Plastics In Non-Primary Forms 59 Chemical Materials & Products N.E.S. 61 Leather, Leather Manufactures N.E.S & Dressed Furskins 62 Rubber Manufactures N.E.S. 63 Cork & Wood Manufactures (Excluding Furniture) 64 Paper, Paperboard & Manufactures Thereof 65 Textile Yarn, Fabrics, Made Up Articles Etc 66 Non-Metallic Mineral Manufactures N.E.S. 67 Iron & Steel 68 Non-Ferrous Metals 69 Manufactures Of Metal N.E.S. 71 Power Generating Machinery & Equipment 72 Machinery Specialized For Particular Industries 73 Metalworking Machinery 74 General Industrial Machinery & Eqp. & Machine… 75 Office Machines & Adp Machines 76 Telecomms & Sound Recording & Reproducing App.… 77 Ele Machinery, App & Appliances & Ele Pt Thereof… 78 Road Vehicles (Including Air Cushion Vehicles) 79 Other Transport Equipment 81 P/Fab Buildings;Sanit.,Plumbing,Heating &Lighting Fixt. 82 Furniture & Parts Thereof; Bedding, Mattresses Etc 83 Travel Goods, Handbags & Similar Containers 84 Articles Of Apparel & Clothing Accessories 85 Footwear 87 Professional, Scientific & Controlling Ins & App N.E.S. 88 Photographic & Optical Goods, N.E.S.; Watches &… 89 Miscellaneous Manufactured Articles N.E.S. 9 Commodities not classified elsewhere; Offa’s Gap Page Figure 18: the key Welsh export sectors 22 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% Source: HMRC Figure 17: Welsh Goods Exports by Sector, 2010 Offa’s Gap Page 23 The Welsh Growth Enigma Two puzzles emerge from the preceding account of the Welsh economy over the last fifteen years: • Firstly, why hasn’t the crisis revealed in the fundamentals of the Welsh economy – productivity, investment, profitability – been reflected in a serious collapse in incomes? • Secondly, why hasn’t the robust recovery of Welsh traded goods – at least as suggested by the HMRC data – been reflected in an improvement in economic growth given the supposed importance of the export base? Answering the first question is relatively straightforward. The effects of the decline in Welsh economic output have been cushioned by transfer payments from outside Wales. This has allowed disposable income to remain much higher than the figures for GDP which is presumably why the current Welsh Government prefers disposable income per head as an economic indicator for relative prosperity. Figure 19: The Disposable Argument Disposable income has declined over this period, from a high point of 93.1% in 1977 (this is equivalent to 95% in terms of household disposable income which includes the non-profit sector) to a lowpoint of 85.8% in 1999 before recovering slightly to its current level of 87.9%. This is a much more moderate decline than that in relative GDP per head. The difference between disposable income and GDP per head is explained by the redistributive effects of transfer payments (both public and private) and a somewhat progressive tax system. Figure 20 shows pensions and social security benefits as a percentage of total household income over the period 1984-2009. From the figure we can see that Offa’s Gap Page 24 transfer payments have risen by over 8% as a share of total income over a period of twenty years. This shift from primary to secondary income has effectively ameliorated the effect of the deterioration in output growth, but with both the pension system and the Welfare state facing a leaner financial environment the continued efficacy of this damping mechanism is in doubt. 32.0% 30.0% 28.0% 26.0% 24.0% 22.0% 20.0% 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 % of total household income Pensions and social security benefits, Wales Source: ONS Figure 20: The Dependent State The second question is more difficult to answer definitively because we only have data on the overseas exports of manufactured goods. Gains in that sector may be cancelled out by what is likely to be a deficit in trade in services. More significant still though is the role played by the inter-regional balance of trade with the other countries and regions of the UK. Because of the “home market” effect, trade with the rest of the UK is certain to have a much bigger share in Welsh GVA than overseas trade. The few studies that have been conducted of the UK regional balance of trade have concluded that Wales has a trade deficit with the UK with estimates ranging, in constant prices, from £2.7 billion in 1964 to £5.5 billion in 1980 falling to some £3.7 billion in 1987.9 Based on the residuals in the analysis in Chart 1 it is reasonable to infer that the deficit in trade with the rest of the UK ballooned as a proportion of GDP by the middle of the 90s when compared with a decade earlier, up from 10% of GDP to well over 20%, before being choked off again by lower rates of economic growth.10 The total current account deficit in Wales during the period 1996-1999 would seem to have reached £5 billion, before recovering somewhat to just under £4 billion by the end of the decade. Report of the Study Group on the role of Public Finances in European integration, vol. II: Chapter 1: United Kingdom, by A.J. Brown, Brussels, 1972; PA Cambridge Economics study quoted in H. Armstrong, J. Taylor Regional Economics and Policy, Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1993 10 It is reasonable to assume that the improvement in net trade to the rest of the UK during the latter half of the 90s was caused by a diminution in imports rather than an export boom as the latter would have resulted in a significant increase in earnings and profits, and therefore in consumption and investment, that are not indicated by the figures. 9 Offa’s Gap Page 25 In some ways these twin deficits – the deficit of Government spending in Wales over taxation, and the deficit of exports generated in Wales to imported goods and services – are in some sense two sides of the same coin. They are also both long-standing features of the Welsh economic predicament, and are strongly interrelated: the bigger the current account deficit in Wales, the bigger the central government money needed to fund the incomes necessary for the private consumption of imported goods and services. So why the worsening of Wales’ position in the mid to late 1990s? The traditional factors which tend to be the subject of policy discussion – Wales’ high economic inactivity rate, its age structure and its unemployment rate – while still important in understanding part of the shortfall in absolute GVA compared with other parts of the UK, have not changed sharply over the last twenty years and thus have not contributed materially to the relative decline in GVA. So what other reasons might there be? Insufficient evidence means we can only make educated guesses but it seems reasonable to suggest that the Welsh economy suffered a dual external shock in the 1990s. The first arose from the loss of its overseas markets due to a change in the terms of trade. The secondary shock arose from the loss of its domestic customers – manufacturing customers in the rest of the UK – themselves reeling from the same process of deindustrialization. The Welsh economy overall, it would seem, has proved significantly less agile in responding to the challenges of structural change than other parts of the UK. What Is To Be Done? This in Wales’ case is the £64 billion question – which is roughly what our output would be if we matched the UK’s prosperity levels. Detailed proposals on a policy programme will be the proper subject of later reports and analyses during the course of this Commission. In this short report we have presented a particular narrative of the Welsh economy that prioritises the role of the export-generating sector of the economy. There are alternative narratives that would emphasise different aspects: skills and productivity, innovation and R&D, jobs, the labour market and demographics, all of which would involve different policy priorities. In this initial report we have concentrated on understanding the problem. Some people might respond by saying this is a waste of time. “We know what the problem is. We need answers.” But how we analyse the problem will be crucial to the development of the right solutions. The narrative presented here, for example, invites certain policy conclusions (see Box A). Offa’s Gap Page 26 A Potential Policy Approach Firstly, a Welsh growth strategy by definition must be a Welsh export strategy. Jobs and incomes in the non-tradable sectors of the economy ultimately depend upon the income generated in the tradable sector. Expanding and diversifying the Welsh export base is critical to increasing the Welsh economic growth rate, and reducing the dependence on budgetary transfers from central government. Wales needs a dedicated arms-length business-friendly agency working to attract export-oriented investment and support and encourage indigenous based exporters. An important part of the strategy will be identifying key niche areas in which Wales can enjoy competitive advantage as part of a strategy of smart specialisation. Secondly, a key part of any export-oriented economic strategy will be to devise an appropriate plan to maximize the economic opportunity offered by our nearest and biggest neighbour, England - a highvalue market, 45 million people of which are within two hours travelling time of Wales. The Welsh public and private sectors need to pool their intelligence and resources in seeking to sell Welsh goods and services to England. The appallingly low participation of Welsh firms in the Olympic Games is symptomatic of a systematic failure by the Welsh economy to adapt to the changing nature of opportunities within the wider UK economy. Particular thought should be given to the opportunities offered in the public sector, including potential new opportunities which may arise out of the privatisation policies in health and education being pursued by the Westminster Government. While these policies themselves find little support in Wales, is it not legitimate to consider whether Welsh firms or not-for-profit enterprises could build on Wales’ extensive knowledge in health and education provision – due to our extensive specialisation in this area – by marketing their services in the English arena? A further possibility might be the creation of publicly-owned Welsh enterprises bidding for some of these contracts. This would not be wholly unprecedented given the Norwegian-owned Statkraft or Swedish state-owned Vattenfall investing in Welsh renewables. The third and final area of policy prioritisation should be the services and infrastructure that the Welsh tradable goods and services sector needs to be successful. The most obvious of these is transport. The new economic geography, most closely associated with the work of Paul Krugman, has emphasized the key role played by transport costs in explaining the relative success of regional economies. The economic historian Nick Crafts has drawn attention in his work to the role played by the shift away from water as the main artery for goods transport – in which Wales, with its good access to ports, had an advantage over the landlocked English midlands – towards rail and particularly roads in the relative decline of the Welsh economy in the 20th century. The low level of investment in Welsh transport Offa’s Gap Page 27 infrastructure – consistently just 2% of transport investment overall – is reflected in a completely unelectrified railway system, an ailing national airport, a Severn rail tunnel that is prone to flooding and a main southern motorway that is vulnerable to a two-lane pinch-point – the Brynglas tunnel - that is the subject of increasingly vociferous business complaints. The composition of Welsh goods exports – petroleum, iron and steel and large-sale turbine equipment – all of which are more likely to be exported by large companies in bulk through ports suggests that the transport infrastructure for land-based transportation of smaller volumes of output by SMEs is a problem area which needs to be addressed. Studies commissioned by the Welsh Government have confirmed travelling distance from the main urban conurbations in the UK as a significant factor in explaining the Welsh economic performance deficit vis-à-vis the UK.11 A comprehensive connectivity strategy to invest in the public infrastructure necessary for a successful export sector – including the quality of broadband connection needed by high value service businesses – should logically be a key supporting element in Welsh economic strategy. Box A Some of the prescriptions in Box A will be controversial for a variety of reasons. What about the emphasis on export promotion versus import substitution through local procurement? Is it morally acceptable to benefit economically from misguided policies of English privatisation? Does viewing transport primarily as a conduit for the export of goods mean reverting to the West-East extractive bias that has so long skewed the development of our national infrastructure? A national economic strategy worthy of the name must be the subject of vigorous debate; at times, impassioned disagreement; but most importantly of all, dialogue. The strategy will not write itself. We need all of Wales to be engaged, if all of Wales is to be transformed. It’s time to get involved. You can contact the Commission: By email: [email protected] By post: The Economic Commission, Plaid Cymru. Anson Court, Atlantic Wharf, Cardiff. CF10 4AL By phone: 029 2047 2272 Understanding productivity variations between Wales and the rest of the UK Report to the Economic Research Advisory Panel, Welsh Assembly Government, Martin Boddy, University of the West of England, Bristol , 2006. 11