References
Transcription
References
Editorial Board Wojciech Czakon (head), Aldona Frączkiewicz-Wronka, Janina Harasim, Grzegorz Kończak, Małgorzata Pańkowska, Andrzej Piosik, Adam Samborski, Sławomir Smyczek, Maja Szymura-Tyc, Tadeusz Trzaskalik, Urszula Zagóra-Jonszta, Patrycja Klimas (secretary) Programming Committee Danuše Bauerová, Antonio Cartelli, Józef Dziechciarz, Bohdan Gruchman, Günter Hofbauer, Natalia P. Ketova, Natalja Lace, Jorma Larimo, Victor N. Ovchinnikov, Maria Romanowska, Frederic Le Roy, Reiner Springer, Heinz-Dietrich Steinmeyer Publishing editor Patrycja Keller Printed by EXPOL P. Rybiński, J. Dąbek Spółka Jawna ul. Brzeska 4, 87-800 Włocławek © Copyright by Publishing House of The University of Economics in Katowice 2014 ISSN 1732-1948 Edition: 160 copies Original version of the Journal of Economics & Management is the paper version All rights reserved. Unauthorised reproduction or adaptation by any means in whole or in part is forbidden Publishing House of the University of Economics in Katowice ul. 1 Maja 50, 40-287 Katowice, tel. (032) 257-76-33, fax (032) 257-76-43 www.wydawnictwo.ue.katowice.pl, e-mail: [email protected] Jerzy Niem mczyk, Ewa Stańczyk-Hu S giet COOPERA ATIVE AND COMPETITIV C VE RELATION NSHIPS IN HIGH EDUCATION E N SECTOR IN N POLAND .................................................................. 5 Anna Lipk ka, Stanisław Waszczak, Alicja A Winnick ka-Wejs LOYALTY Y AND WORK KAHOLISM IN N THE METH HODS OF HU UMAN CAPIT TAL EVALUAT TION (IN) AN N ORGANIZA ATION – A CO OMPARATIVE E STUDY ................. 25 Dominikaa Latusek-Jurcczak, Kaja Prrystupa-Rząd dca COLLABO ORATION AN ND TRUST-B BUILDING IN N OPEN INN NOVATION COMMUN NITY ............................................................................................................................. 47 Frédéric Le L Roy, Famaara Hyacinthee Sanou DOES CO OOPETITION N STRATEGY Y IMPROVE MARKET M PE ERFORMANC CE? AN EMPIR RICAL STUD DY IN MOBIL LE PHONE IN NDUSTRY ........................................ 63 K Patrycja Klimas MULTIFA ACETED NAT TURE OF CO OOPETITION N INSIDE AN N AVIATION N SUPPLY CHAIN C – THE E CASE OF THE T AVIATIO ON VALLEY Y................................... 95 Wojciech Czakon, C Karo olina Mucha--Kuś, Mariuszz Rogalski COOPETIITION RESEA ARCH LAND DSCAPE – A SYSTEMATIC S C LITERATU URE REVIEW W 1997-2010 ....................................................................................... 121 Jerzy Niemczyk Ewa Stańczyk‐Hugiet Wroclaw University of Economics, Poland COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS IN HIGH EDUCATION SECTOR IN POLAND J ERZY N IEMCZYK , E WA S TAŃCZYK -HUGIET Abstract Coopetition builds on the idea that firms – competitors cooperate to create values and to appropriate value. Despite extant research on this topic, our understanding about how firms are engaged in cooperative relationships with their rivals is still in its early stages. This paper explores the higher education sector in Poland from the perspective of cooperative and competitive relationships, and analyses its performance on three different levels, i.e. macro, meso, and micro using case-based insights to answer the question(s). We propose that cooperative relationships amongst a variety of different universities increase their competitiveness and enhance the diffusion of knowledge. In the long run this translates into benefits for all parties and into a rise in the efficiency of the entire education sector. Keywords: coopetition, competition, cooperation, strategy, university, resource heterogeneity, convergent goals. Introduction We can observe increasingly innovative forms of relationships between competing organizations when we view them through the framework of the cooperative relationship (Czakon, 2012).This makes us believe that the source of competitive advantage, is a set of relationships between the firm and other market players. The organization that sets up such a relationship can be more beneficial in the market. As a result the competition for the relational value is treated as a third leg in the theory of strategy (Contractor, 2002). Research on coopetition is limited mainly to business organizations, however, relations of coopetition can easily be observed in the non-business sectors, for instance in higher education. Siregar, Dagnino, and Garraffo (2011) state: “Connectivity between the concepts of Relationships, Strategy and Resources brings perspectives such as resource based view and relational view into [our] consideration as potential theoretical perspective in explaining coopetition. All the results at the end may affirm coopetitive strategy as a new form of strategy, an alternative to the two other main paradigms – competition and cooperation – that are already corroborated in the field of strategic management”. 6 COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS… The higher education is a unique sector that permits us to observe systems of cooperation and competition, both characteristics of so called coopetition strategy. Moreover, colleges and universities communicate with their environment in a natural way. This communication process takes place through: students, that in the vast majority are employed in surrounding areas; staff, who are carrying out research for outside companies and teams of researchers, which are working together with outside companies as well as within the framework of the university’s general procedures and so they are developing interconnected links with surrounding businesses and companies so establishing an cooperative relationships. In almost laboratory conditions, we mean case-based insights individual variants of relationships are possible to be analysed and assessed qualitatively in terms of their effectiveness and efficiency. This article aims to diagnose the current state of cooperative and competitive relationships within the academic environment and suggests what future might be. The reasoning visualizes that we undertake the identification of the type of the relationship between the organizations in the researched sector. In other words the concept of the paper refers to the identification of the types of relationships. This is particularly important since such a relationship has not been observed yet. 1. Coopetition in strategic management literature In the world of business many companies decide to take not only competitive actions, but also actions, which rely on cooperation with other competitors. Research conducted by A. Brandenburger and B. Nalebuff (1996) likewise G. Dagnino and G. Padula (2002), amongst others, present situations where competitive and cooperative actions appear simultaneously. Research on coopetition has been increasing rapidly in recent years and the very concept has been used to clarify the economic and social effects of networking in various sectors and countries (de Ngo, and Okura, 2008). Until 1996, studies on coopetition were limited to proposals of A. Brandenburger and B. Nalebuff (1996). Since the mid-90s of 20 century however many more publications focusing on this subject have become available, such as: dyadic coopetition between two entities (Bengtsson, Kock, 2000), heterogeneous coopetition (e.g. Luo, 2004) and inter-organizational coopetition (e.g. Amburgey and Rao, 1996; Tsai, 2002; Luo, Slotegraaf and Pan, 2006). G. Hamel et al. (1989) treat coopetition as a continuation and natural consequence of competition. Cooperation and competition can therefore be per 7 J ERZY N IEMCZYK , E WA S TAŃCZYK -HUGIET ceived as the phases of the organization’s life cycle. M. Bengtsson and S. Kock (2000) suggest that the benefit companies derive from coopetition is an effect of the combination of the pressure of competitors (effect of the competition), with an ability to access greater resources (effect of the cooperation Coopetition is defined as "a system of actors operating on the basis of the partial compliance of interests and purposes". It is an approach that is still developing, allowing for new and different examinations into the field of strategic management (Dagnino et al., 2008). Coopetition, claims W.Czakon, is a particular object of study, requiring a specific theoretical approach (Czakon, 2009). In general terms, coopetition is a strategy of joint value creation, a strategy of competition in the distribution of values in conditions of a partial similarity of purposes and the changeable structure of the positive-sum game (Dagnino et al., 2008). In A. Lado’s, as well as M. Bengtsson and S. Kock’s (2000) opinion, it is these two significant forces, the pressure of competition and desire for cooperation – that constitute coopetition, allowing for a rare situations in which competitors show the initiative directed at rent-seeking (Lado et al., 1997). Coopetiton is also “driven” by the need for strategic flexibility. Many studies have focused on the search for an innovative benefit in innovation-related coopetition, or simply in innovation networks (Ritala, Hurmelinna-Laukkanen, 2009). These studies are conducted mainly in business enterprises and rarely in other types of organizations (Lundberg, Andresen, 2012). It is possible, however, to find examples of coopetition in the education sector in several research projects – International research collaboration: opportunities for the UK higher education sector, 2008; Review of closer collaboration between universities and major publicly funded research agencies, 2004 (Commonwealth of Australia, 2004); Lundberg, Andresen, 2012. How do we study co-opetition in practice? Research on coopetition has theoretical character largely. Listed authors attempt to offer coopetition classifications and models (Luo’s studies, 2004, 2006, 2007; Rusko, 2011, p. 311-320; Mention, 2011, p. 44-53). 2. Research concept In this study, Kenworthy’s method of distinguishing levels of micro, macro and meso coopetition is used (Kenworthy, 2005). The level of macro coopetition refers to the relation between groups of organizations, including those from various sectors. The meso level refers to vertical and horizontal relationships amongst organizations. The micro level concentrates on the entities within the organizations. 8 COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS… Most studies focus only on inter-organizational network ties and do not incorporate into their research the effect of interpersonal relationships, which can also facilitate economic interactions between organizations (Ingram and Roberts, 2000). The basic question concerns the benefits, in terms of knowledge and economic value that we receive from every type of relation. For the purpose of this study three important variables have been considered: interests and goals, relations, and resources. As Branderburger and Nalebuff propose coopetition/coopetition strategy is characterized by partially convergent interests and goals and this view has been widely accepted by researchers since 1996. The relations between partners are another important attribute determining cooperation. The importance of relations in building a competitive advantage is highlighted by a resource-based view (Barney, 1991). Relations are a source of competitive advantages. They who have the valuable resources win a competitive advantage. Relational capital between partners in a network of relationships can foster cooperative relationship, as it creates a basis for learning and knowledge transfer on the one hand, and curbs opportunistic behaviour so preventing the leakage of critical knowledge, on the other. Therefore, relational capital can enable competition and co-operation to co-exist. The overall goal for firms to cooperate with other firms is to strengthen their competitive positions by inter-partner learning and by obtaining valuable resources from their cooperative relationships. This is recognized in both the literature on alliances (e.g. Parkhe, 1993; Reuer and Tong, 2010) and coopetition (e.g. Gnyawali and Madhavan 2001; Luo, 2007). Papers written on alliances (thoroughly) described how firms achieve stronger competitive positions by cooperating with other firms through: internalizing partner skills and resources (Ahuja, 2000; Prahalad and Hamel, 1990; Oum et al., 2004), learning from partners (Dussauge, Garrette and Mitchell, 2000), knowledge sharing and creation (Inkpen, 2000; Khanna, Gulati and Nohria, 1998), growth in size and market share (Oliver, 2001; Reuer and Tong, 2010), protection from radical new innovations which will erode a firm’s competitive position (Rothaermel, 2001; Afuah, 2000), sharing the risks and costs of research and development (Hagedoorn, 2002; Ouchi and Bolton, 1988), raising entry barriers (Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven, 1996) and creating economies of scale (Koh and Venkatraman, 1991; Garrette, Castaner and Dussauge, 2009; and Yami et al., 2010). Gulati (Gulati, Singh, 1999) develops the notion of network resources, which refer to those resources that emerge from a firm being embedded in inter- 9 J ERZY N IEMCZYK , E WA S TAŃCZYK -HUGIET firm networks. Other studies show that network resources are particularly important to a firm's acquisition of competitive capabilities (McEvily and Zaheer, 1999) because network resources offer valuable information about new business opportunities (Gulati, Singh, 1999). Regarding the resource-benefit of the cooperative relationship, the main aspect discussed by some researchers is, that it is best if the variety of resources available in the organisations environment is use together in order to survive the demanding and changing environment (Tsai, Fang, and Lin, 2005). Cooperation between firms occurs when they present economic benefits for each other rather than the result of the alliance meaning that costs associated with acquiring resources in the market or developing them internally are incurred (Williamson, 1991). Typically, the type of association in collaborations is tilted towards partial interdependence, in which the firm uses cooperative arrangements with other firms to attain its objectives. Heterogeneity in resources can foster coopetitive relationships, because unique and complementary resources can be advantageous both for co-operation and competition. In a typical network, three types of resource flows take place between partners – information flows, asset flows, and status flows – and firms’ ability to access and use network resources varies depending on their structural position in the network (Gnyawali and Madhavan, 2001). 3. Research framework and methodology The study assumes three levels analysis of the types of relationship. The first level is a macro level between universities and the environment, mainly business. The second level is between universities and the third is level is between university departments, inside organizations. On all these levels, factors that may affect the increase in the quality of the relationships will be examined. The research assumes that these factors are: the degree of similarity of the objectives, the type of relationship binding the main participants and the degree of resource diversity on both/all sides. 10 COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS… Figure 1. Conceptual model Meso Macro •similarity of the objectives •type of relation •resource diversity •similarity of the objectives •type of relation •resource diversity Micro •similarity of the objectives •type of relation •resource diversity Coopetition In particular, at the value of the macro level relies on communication and information flow as well as generating inter-sector knowledge and the transference of this information. This results in the possibility of accumulating knowledge. The value in this case is obtained by reducing aggressive and suboptimal rent-seeking, and by agreeing on sharing both benefits and funds. Relationspis of the university and contextual surrounding strengthens their competitiveness, but also affects the synergy between the competitive parties (Bizzi and Langley, 2012). Therefore, we ask the following question: Q1: Does a higher level of convergent interests and goals between the university and business environment lead to a higher level of cooperation? Q2: Does the sense of cooperation between the university and business environment dominate in terms of their relationship? Q3: Will heterogeneity in resources between the university and business environment lead to coopetition? In our opinion, answering these questions helps identify the types of relationships between universities and business organizations. The chosen way to identify this type of relationship enables us to determine whether in this case, the relationship between these entities is simultaneous competition and cooperation, or if there is only cooperation between them. 11 J ERZY N IEMCZYK , E WA S TAŃCZYK -HUGIET At the meso level, the value can be seen in the results of intra-sector creation and transfer of new knowledge, deep communication and the flow of information as well as joint action on co-development. Coopetition of many differing varieties of universities increases their competitiveness and enhances the diffusion of knowledge, and in the long run, translates into benefits for all coopetitive sides and a rise in efficiency rise throughout the entire education sector. Therefore, we ask the following question: Q4: Will higher levels of convergent interest and goal between universities lead to higher level of cooperation? Q5: Will higher levels of cooperation between universities lead to increased level development throughout the education sector (meso coopetition level)? Q6: Will heterogeneity in resources between universities lead to coopetition (equal competition and collaboration) At the micro level, where value is added through an extensive system of communication and information flow, and through the creation and transfer of new knowledge within an organization, the economic benefits (economic value) are obtained through greater involvement of all stakeholders of the organization (Enz and Lambert, 2012; Bizzi and Langley, 2012). Cooperation between many different departments and units can influence the rise in their level of effectiveness, In order to answer this we must first look at the following questions: Q7: Will higher levels of convergent interest and goals between departments and researchers lead to higher level of cooperation between departments (cooperation – dominated)? Q8: Will higher levels of competition between departments and researchers lead to higher levels of faculty (school) effectiveness? Q9: Will heterogeneity in resources between departments and researchers lead to coopetition (equal competition and collaboration)? Referring to resource diversity we follow Bengtsson and Kock thesis: “Heterogeneity in resources can foster coopetitive relationships, as unique resources can be advantageous both for cooperation and competition” (2000, p. 421). Finding the complex results need in order to answer these questions, using the available data and information, is almost impossible. The main obstacle is the lack of possibilities in comparing in similar operating conditions. Practically 12 COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS… speaking, in order to fully answer these questions a sample of mature sectors in established Polish universities would have to be available for research. Such a situation will more than likely only be possible in about 10 years as currently the higher education sector and in particular the economics department is in a process of growth and development, triggered by implementing new changes in how it functions in Poland. 4. Sample characteristics and methods As of 1 March 2014 in Poland there were 5 public universities and 38 faculties of economics at other public universities (16 at universities, 18 at polytechnics and 4 at the agricultural colleges) operating. In addition, nearly 150 private higher education institutions educating in the field of economics and 25 public vocational schools educating at the first cycle of studied, mainly in the field of management were operating. The largest and most important “players” in the market include: University of Economics in Katowice, Cracow University of Economics, Poznan University of Economics, Warsaw School of Economics, Wroclaw University of Economics. As of 30 November 2010, 59,184 students were enrolled in these five universities. A total of 415,559 – students were studying in the field of economic and administrative sciences at public universities in Poland. This means ca. 2/3 of all students in Poland (the total of 1,841,251) were studying (CSO, 2011). Other statistics which show the study of economics in relation to the rest of the higher education sector are unable to be used for analysis owing to the specific nature of the study of economic. These specific features are: a very low level of expenditure needed for educating an individual student in comparison to other types of colleges, a high percentage of part-time students – nearly 50% and a low statistical citation rate in the field of social sciences. All these factors make the study of economic very hermetic in a sense. The five most important business schools in Poland are representative for the Polish higher education. These universities have a decisive influence on the level of both economics and management and the quality of those graduating with economics in Poland. They will also be subject for exploration in the context of the stated hypotheses. There are 23 departments in five business colleges in Poland. A further 38 economic departments exist in other private higher education institutions. In total, in public universities there are 51 departments grouping ca 200 chairs, 13 J ERZY N IEMCZYK , E WA S TAŃCZYK -HUGIET bringing nearly 2,500 researchers and PhD students. These employees work independently conducting research, which may result in some 5,000 scientific articles, monographs and chapters in books per year. The HEI sector, in particular the economic department in Poland is a highly competitive sector. It is difficult for a natural cooperation. This follows from the fact that virtually all of its revenues comes from teaching activities (the subsidy and tuition fees from non-full-time students). Therefore, each student recruited actually means more revenue. And every school is a real competitor. The number of students ranges from 10 thousand at Warsaw School of Economics to 21 thousand at Cracow University of Economics (2010). This illustrates the differences in the activity of recruiting departments. Data used in the work was obtained from different research methods. They were primarily unstructured interviews with the staff of the analysed business schools, as well as primary data from different reports and financial statements from analysed business schools. The different data was then compared in order to eliminate factual inaccuracies. The study used comparative analysis and presentation of the usual techniques of quantitative data. 5. Macro level analysis The macro level concerns the analysis of the relationships between universities and the business environment. This relationship is still in its infancy and is mainly limited to the use of resources offered by both partners in teaching activities. A high degree of convergent interest and goals has to be dealt with. In most Western universities, this type of relation is also one of the most common. Analysis of five universities’ and careers offices’ websites selected for the study show that these universities are connected to about 20 global companies which offer their student work programs. The second area of cooperation is in applied research, undertaken at the request of individual companies. The situation of analysed universities differs substantially from other universities. In case of economic HEIs the competition for research grants is great and completely differs from the competition for grants from departments at other colleges. Apart from colleges, global consulting companies, small and medium enterprises advising in the area of finances, accounting, management, logistics, etc. and of course companies’ own developmental departments seek to receive contracts from the business domain. 14 COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS… A report prepared by the staff of the University of Economics in Katowice emphasizes these facts and indicates that companies "are mostly not interested in the implementation of joint research (66% negative responses), nor in participating in the process of education (65%) or providing university students and graduates with placements (55%). They are moderately (30-40% of responses) interested in consulting, expertise and training conducted for their benefit by university staff” (Model współpracy uczelni..., 2010). A rapid development of consultancy conducted by university research staff outside the formal framework of the university is a significant specificity of Polish economic HEIs. Most research staff working for business colleges is or will be also working in a business or as a business consultant. This results from the specificity of teaching and research activity, as well as from an economic necessity caused by the low rate of pay for salaries, and competitive salaries in the private consulting sector. Such connections unquestionably improve the quality of research and teaching processes. Previous studies show the positive impact of better coordination and increased diversity of resources for the cooperating parties (Garcia and Velasco, 2002). Coopetition also means an access to external knowledge (Spence, Coles, and Harris, 2001) and coordination of organizational learning, particularly through an access to the partner's core competencies (Bengtsson and Kock 2000). From a strategic point of view the cooperation with competitors gives the opportunity to be more flexible and more responsive to the environment. Coopetition also has potential costs, such as losing control of key activities, information and resources (Håkanson and Ford, 2002). Similar challenges are faced with regards to relationships between colleges and business companies. The recruitment activity of global businesses is conducted virtually in all business colleges in Poland and is another example of cooperation, especially as a few from these global businesses have own colleges located outside Poland. It is also interesting to look at those companies whose business and capabilities prove to be a useful resource for the educational establishment they have a relationship with. The clearest example of this can be seen when looking at financial pulling power of both partners. The business is a party in possession of a financial surplus. According to research commissioned by EandY in 2008, Research and Development activities in Poland take place mainly in the public sector. 60% of the expenditure on Research and Development was financed by the state, while in the EU it was 40%, and in case of OECD countries – 34% (OECD, 2008; Wolszczak-Derlacz and Parteka, 2008). 15 J ERZY N IEMCZYK , E WA S TAŃCZYK -HUGIET Universities in Poland have reduced financial resources. An interesting example of cooperation can be seen in research where scientists who have knowledge and skills that the company’s staff do not possess, benefit from the knowledge of these companies which is often stored in the form of databases, specific knowledge and secret knowledge. This is particularly true of research in the area of macro-economics and finance. Unfortunately, such forms of cooperation in Poland are still rare. Such relationship always benefits and costs both parties. Whilst there are many positive examples, it is also possible to find a lot of negative attempts to use “the competition and cooperation”. Many companies use their position of power to forcing universities which are in a disadvantage position to take certain actions, such as forcing a university to place their funds on developing practices and departments which focus on the needs and practices of that particular company. The observations carried out in five business universities after the reforms present a very high willingness to change; there is an annual double-digit rise in the share of the external research funding and a growing participation in the teaching process of business specialists. The identification of the types of relationships at the macro-level seems problematic, since the research activity outside the university cannot be a measure of coopetition between universities and organizations from the business environment. It is because the activity in this field indicates the relationship of cooperation. 6. Meso level analysis The area of research activities is becoming more competitive. Limited budgetary resources are being divided by the National Science Centre according to a criteria, which is based on multiple teams of researchers who existing in competition with one another. Though there are funding bodies which, favour research carried out jointly by several centres, however they are in the minority in Polish economical schools and almost seem like a symbolic gesture of cooperation rather than anything else. In Poland, research is customarily conducted individually, in contrast to other Western countries, where most research is collaborative. The activities of five major business schools give a few examples of cooperation, such as: joint research conferences, and textbooks and scholarly monographs written by research teams. The lack of joint research, as well as the small number of individual research programs, is the result of the fact that researchers are overloaded with 16 COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS… teaching work. This is particularly evident in the economic universities, which are oriented towards financing their activities with tuition fees. This is confirmed by the previously quoted evidence of studies carried out by EandY. A negative correlation between the teaching burden and research productivity of the staff has been observed. The conclusion is that research and teaching are in fact more competitive, than complementary (Wolszczak-Derlacz and Parteka, 2008). 7. Micro level analysis In conditions when autarky, but also maintaining high competitiveness is ineffective, a partnership can turn out to be the success factor between members of interacting organizations. According to P. Bourdieu, social capital, which came into existence as a result of having durable networks of relations, is a collection of resources supported by a mutual acquaintance and recognition, and participation in such an organized network provides each of its members support in the form of resources – including relational – which is owned by the whole group (Bourdieu, 1985). In this regard, each member of the network becomes a kind of node, the agent making their own relational resources available to other members of network. In this way an existing multi-directional plain of contact enhances the possibilities of the partnership, and each of the entities involved are a potential node, enabling the further expansion of the network. Anything which connects with other operators of within the same environment, regardless of their position and the nature of the relationship may become a node. Collaborating teams are most often grouped around independent researchers having considerable research achievements and/or academic position, and most often solve research problems from narrow research sub disciplines. More and more of these horizontal structures can be noticed among young staff working mainly in a virtual environment. In the future, there will be more such examples. Rules for financing research projects have impact on that. Both the financial resources coming from the government and the European Union prefer teams composed of researchers from different backgrounds. It is also possible to find examples of excessive competition (rat race) that blocks the creation of systems of cooperation. It is a syndrome of generation Y. Competition leads to the department’s development measured in: the number of research activities carried out, degrees obtained and the quality of the teaching process and position in the market. Unfortunately, in the majority of 17 J ERZY N IEMCZYK , E WA S TAŃCZYK -HUGIET Polish economic universities two examples of activities can be observed. The first is limiting the faculties and departments ability to collaborate and pursue strategies of independence (autarky). Understanding the simple rules of synergy is often difficult. Increased ability of implementing the principle of synergy may result from of the competition between researchers for research grants. Analysis of applications submitted to the National Science Centre; show a dynamically growing research activity in academic staff. Also, activities within a network of contacts may surprisingly increase such activities. In practice, researchers, not only the Polish ones, have very narrow specializations. Such a solution should therefore contribute to linking diverse knowledge and skills while maintaining the possibility of competing for other resources. Examples of such processes can be observed in research and teaching. They are: joint research projects, faculties and teaching specialties led through different departments, joint scientific conferences, a voluntary association of units in the form of institutes, and cyclical administering of the departments’ affairs. However, the limited scope of such solutions, results from the general low financing of science in Poland, which has already been pointed out. Conclusions, recommendations, limitations The aim of cognitive research is to formulate applications of testing the effectiveness of types of relationship at different levels of analysis. Being able to carry out examinations which go beyond the formal boundaries of an organization is especially valuable. Showing possible means of exploiting cooperation benefits and costs from the level meso and macro to the level of the micro organization is another conclusion of these examinations. The greatest difficulty is in proving that the benefits of such collaborations between different parties are in fact beneficial for all and that the sum of the whole is greater than its parts. Changes in the criteria for assessing the effectiveness of higher education, which are now moving in the direction of those criteria used in other Western universities, will foster the growth of cooperation in this regard. Apart from rare examples of collaboration in the form of joint conferences, incidental joint research projects and attempts to implement network possibilities, so as to exchange knowledge, cooperation is practically non-existent. The lowest level of cooperation exists at the micro level. Here too, it is possible to take note of only a few examples of institutional cooperation. Many different forms of cooperation occur at the level of departments and individual employees. However, there exist 18 COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS… the benefits which are offered by relationship networks between researchers and educators, though these exist at a personal/ individual level rather than owing to a formal contractual agreement. To some extent future research approach should be oriented to the network level. Studying coopetition at the network level and maybe the articulation of different levels within the network is good perspective to extent uor understanding of coopetition in higher education sector. Co-location, cluster formation, international and national networking, sharing of infrastructure, co-investment in infrastructure and research, are critical for collaboration. We recognize some limitations of the study, mainly due to the methodology adopted and context as well. This study addresses a specific context. Due to this there is a need for generalization of research finding to allow for further in depth research References Afuah A. (2000): How Much Do Your Coopetitiors’ Capabilities Matter in the Face of Technological Change? “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 21(3), pp. 387-404. Ahuja G. (2000): The Duality of Collaboration: Inducements and Opportunities in the Formation of Interfirm Linkages. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 21, pp. 317-343. Amburgey T. and Rao H. (1996): Organizational Ecology: Past, Present, and Future Directions. “Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 39(5), pp. 1265-1286. Barney J. (1991): Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. “Journal of Management”, No. 17, pp. 99-120. Bengtsson M., Kock S. (2000): Coopetition in Business Networks – to Cooperate and Compete Simultaneously. “Industrial Marketing Management”, Vol. 29, No. 5. Bizzi L., Langley A., (2012): Studying Processes in and Around Networks. “Industrial Marketing Management”, Vol. 41 pp. 224-234. Bourdieu P. (2004): The Forms of Capital. In: Ed. J.G. Richardson: Handbook of Theory and Research for the Sociology of Education. Greenwood, New York. Brandenburger A. and Nalebuff B. (1996): Co-Opetition. Doubleday, New York. Commonwealth of Australia (2004): Review of Closer Collaboration Between Universities and Major Publicly Funded Research Agencies. www.dest.gov.au/collaboration/ documents/pub.pdf. Contactor F. and Beldona S. (2002): Interfirm Learning in Alliances and Technology Networks: An Empirical Study in the Global Pharmaceutical and Chemical Industries. In: Ed. F. Contractor, P. Lorange: Competitive Strategies and Alliances. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam. 19 J ERZY N IEMCZYK , E WA S TAŃCZYK -HUGIET CSO (2011): Higher Education Institutions and Their Financial in 2010. Report, Warsaw. Czakon W. (2009): Koopetycja – splot tworzenia i zawłaszczania wartości. „Przegląd Organizacji”, nr 12. Czakon W. (2012): Sieci w zarządzaniu strategicznym. Wolters Kluwer Polska, Warszawa. Dagnino G.B., Le Roy F., Yami S. and Czakon W. (2008): Strategie koopetycji – nowa forma dynamiki międzyorganizacyjnej. „Przegląd Organizacji”, nr. 6. Dari L. (2009): Third Party Stakeholders: The Key To Coopetition Strategies in the Ready-To-Wear Sector? Tenth International Business Research Conference Dubai, 16-17 April 2009. Dussauge P., Garrette B. and Mitchell W. (2000): Learning From Competing Partners: Outcomes and Durations of Scale and Link Alliances in Europe, North America and Asia. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 21(2), pp. 99-126. Easton G., and Araujo L. (1994): Market Exchange, Social Structures and Time. “European Journal of Marketing”, Vol. 28 (3). Eisenhardt K.M. and Schoonhoven C.B. (1996): Resource-Based View of Strategic Alliance Formation: Strategic and Social Effects in Entrepreneurial Firms. “Organization Science”, Vol. 7(2), pp. 615-634. Enz M.G. and Lambert D.M. (2012): Using Cross-Functional, Cross-Firm Teams to Co-Create Value: The Role of Financial Measures. “Industrial Marketing Management”, Vol. 41, pp. 495-507. Farah A. and Wadhwa A. (2009): Collaborating With Your Rivals: Identifying Sources of Coopetitive Performance. Paper presented at the DRUID Summer Conference 2009. Garcia C. and Velasco C. (2002): Co-Opetition and Performance: Evidence From European Biotechnology Industry. II Annual Conference of EURAM on “Innovative Research Management”, Stockholm, May 9-11, 2002. Garrette B., Castaner X. and Dussauge P. (2009): Horizontal Alliances as an Alternative to Autonomous Production: Product Expansion Mode Choice in the Worldwide Aircraft Industry 1945-2000, “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. (30), pp. 885-894. Gnyawali D. and Madhavan R. (2001): Cooperative Networks and Competitive Dynamics: A Structural Embeddedness Perspective. “Academy of Management Review”, Vol. 26(3). pp. 31-449. Gnyawali D., He J. and Madhavan R. (2006): Impact of Co-opetition on Firm Competitive Behavior: An Empirical Examination. “Journal of Management” August, Vol. 32, pp. 507-530. Gulati R. and Singh H. (1999): The Architecture of Cooperation: Managing Coordination Costs and Appropriation Concerns in Strategic Alliance. “Administrative Science Quarterly”, Vol. 43(4), pp. 781-814. 20 COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS… Hagedoorn J. (2002): Inter-firm RandD Partnerships: An Overview of Major Trends and Patterns Since 1960. “Research Policy”, Vol. 31, pp. 477-492. Håkansson H. and Ford D. (2002): How Should Companies Interact in Business Networks. “Journal of Business Research”, Vol. 55, pp. 133-139. Hamel G., Doz Y. and Prahalad C.K. (1989): Collaborate with Your Competitors and Win. “Harvard Business Review”, Vol. 67, No. 1, pp. 133-139. Hampden-Turner Ch. and Trompenaars A. (2000): Siedem kultur kapitalizmu. Dom Wydawniczy ABC, Kraków. Ingram P. and Roberts P.W. (2000): Friendships among Competitors in the Sydney Hotel Industry. “The American Journal of Sociology”, Vol. 106(2), pp. 387-423. Inkpen A.C. (2000): Learning Through Joint Ventures: A Framework of Knowledge Acquisition. “Journal of Management Studies”, Vol. 37, pp. 1019-1043. International Research Collaboration: Opportunities for the UK Higher Education Sector (2008). Universities UK. Kenworthy L. (1995): In Search of National Economic Success. Balancing Competition and Cooperation. Sage, Thousand Oaks. Khanna T., Gulati R. and Nohria N. (1998): The Dynamics of Learning Alliances: Competition, Cooperation, and Relative Scope. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 19, pp. 193-210. Koh J. and Venkatraman N. (1991): Joint Venture Formations and Stock Market Reactions: Assessment in the Information Technology Sector. “The Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 34, (4), pp. 869-892. Koh J. and Venkatraman N. (1991): Joint Venture Formations and Stock Market Reactions: An Assessment in the Information Technology Sector. “Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 34 Iss. 4. Lado A.A., Boyd N.G. and Hanlon S.C. (1997): Competition, Cooperation and the Search for Economic Rents: A Syncretic Model. “Academy of Management Review”, No. 22, pp. 110-141. Lundberg H. and Andresen E. (2012): Cooperation Among Companies, Universities and Local Government in a Swedish Context. “Industrial Marketing Management”, Vol. 41, pp. 429-437. Luo X., Slotegraaf R.J. and Pan X. (2006): Cross-Functional ‘Co-Opetition’: The Simultaneous Role of Cooperation and Competition Within Firms. “Journal of Marketing”, Vol. 70, pp. 67-80. Luo Y. (2004): Coopetition in International Business. Copenhagen Business School Press, Copenhagen. Luo Y. (2007): Coopetition Perspective of Global Competition. “Journal of World Business”, Vol. 42, pp. 129-144. 21 J ERZY N IEMCZYK , E WA S TAŃCZYK -HUGIET McEvily B. and Zaheer A. (1999): Bridging Ties: A Source of Firm Heterogeneity in Competitive Capabilities. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 20, pp. 1133-1156. Mention A.-L. (2011): Co-Operation and Co-Opetition as Open Innovation Practices in the Service Sector: Which Influence on Innovation Novelty? “Technovation”, No. 31, pp. 44-53. Model współpracy uczelni z otoczeniem biznesowym. 2010, http://bpiwm.ue.katowice.pl/ download/ubico_model_calibri.pdf (10.06.2012). Ngo de D. and Okura M. (2008): Coopetition in a Mixed Duopoly Market. EcoMOd 2008 International Conference on Policy Modeling, Berlin, 2-4 July. Oliver A.L. (2001): Strategic Alliances and the Learning Life-Cycle of Biotechnology Firms. “Organization Studies”, Vol. 22 (3), pp. 467-489. Ouchi W.G. and Bolton M.K. (1988): The Logic of Joint Research and Development. “California Management Review”, Vol. 30 (3), pp. 9-33. Oum T.H., Park J.-H., Kim K. and Yu C. (2004): The Effect of Horizontal Alliances on Firm Productivity and Profitability: Evidence from the Global Airline Industry. “Journal of Business Research”, Vol. 57, pp. 844-853. Padula G. and Dagnino G.B. (2002): Coopetition Strategy a New Kind of Interfirm Dynamics for Value Creation. Paper presented at EURAM – The European Academy of Management Second Annual Conference – Innovative Research in Management Stockholm, 9-11 May 2002, Track Coopetition Strategy. Towards a New Kind of Interfirm Dynamics? http://ecsocman.hse.ru/data/977/644/1219/coopetition.pdf. Padula G. and Dagnino G.B. (2007): Understanding the Rise of Coopetition: The Intrusion of Competition in a Cooperative Game Structure. “International Studies of Management and Organization”, Vol. 37, pp. 32-52. Parkhe A. (1993): Strategic Alliance Structuring: A Game Theoretic and Transaction Cost Examination of Interfirm Cooperation. “The Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 36 (4), pp. 794-829. Prahalad C.K. and Hamel G. (1990): The Core Competence of the Corporation. “Harvard Business Review”, Vol. 68 (3), pp. 79-91. Reuer J. and Tong T.W. (2010): Discovering Valuable Growth Opportunities: An Analysis of Equity Alliances with IPO Firms. “Organization Science”, Vol. 21(1), pp. 202-215. Ritala P. and Hurmelinna-Laukkanen P. (2009): What’s in it for Me? Creating and Appropriating Value in Innovation-Related Coopetition. “Technovation”, Vol 29, No. 12, pp. 819-828. Rothaermel F.T. (2001): Incumbent’s Advantage through Exploiting Complementary Assets via Interfirm Cooperation. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 22, pp. 687-699. Rusko R. (2011): Exploring the Concept of Coopetition: A Typology for the Strategic Moves of the Finnish Forest Industry. “Industrial Marketing Management”, No. 40, pp. 311-320. 22 COOPERATIVE AND COMPETITIVE RELATIONSHIPS… Siregar S.L., Dagnino G.B, and Garraffo F. (2011): Content Analysis and Social Network Analysis: A Two-Phase Methodology in Obtaining Fundamental Concepts of Coopetition. “Jurnal Ilmiah Ekonomi Bisnis”, Vol. 14, No. 2. Spence L., Coles A. and Harris L. (2001): The Forgotten Stakeholder? Ethics and Social Responsibility in Relation to Competitors. “Business and Society Review”, Vol. 106, No. 4, pp. 331-352. Szkoły wyższe i ich finanse w 2010 r. 2011. Raport GUS, Warszawa. Tsai F.S., Fang S.C. and Lin J.L. (2010): Organizational Learning, Social Capital and Technology Transfer: An Empirical Study on Firms Participating RandD Consortia. “Journal of Management”, Vol. 22, No. 3, pp. 433-462. Tsai W. (2002): Social Structure of Coopetition Within a Multiunit Organization, Competition, and Intraorganizational Knowledge Sharing. “Organization Science”, Vol. 13 (2), pp. 179-190. Williamson O.E. (1991): Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives. “Administrative Science Quarterly”, Vol. 36 (2), pp. 269-296. Wit de B., Meyer R. (2007): Synteza strategii. PWE, Warszawa. Wolszczak-Derlacz J. and Parteka A. (2008): Produktywność naukowa wyższych szkół publicznych w Polsce. Bibliometryczna analiza porównawcza. Sprawne Państwo. Ernest and Young, Warszawa. Yami S., Castaldo S., Dagnino G.B. and Le Roy F. (2010): Coopetition. Winning Strategies for the 21st Century. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, England. 23 Anna Lipka, Stanisław Waszczak, Alicja Winnicka‐Wejs University of Economics in Katowice, Poland LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS OF HUMAN CAPITAL EVALUATION (IN) AN ORGANIZATION – A COMPARATIVE STUDY A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS Abstract The aim of the study is to show how selected methods of human capital evaluation determine loyalty and workaholism, the features affecting employees` efficiency. It was found that seven analysed methods of evaluation differ in terms of ways of defining generators and devaluators of human capital value. Based on the conducted analysis, it was found that the historical costs method, the discounted revenue streams method, the HR Balanced Scorecard and the Saarbrücken formula are not suitable for recognition of loyalty and workaholism as behavioral sources constituting the value of human capital. The most useful methods for their recognition were: Mayo monitor, risk – value method and personnel portfolio. The conclusion is that, with the use of the Mayo monitor, the dynamics of loyalty types and the types of workaholics, which correspond to the variable in the monitor, may be captured, forming the skills profile. Also the risk value method may depict a risk map for loyalty and workaholism, for example, to assess the quality of methods and their diagnosis. In turn, the personnel portfolio allows us to determine the dynamics of the share of different types of workaholism and loyalty. Keywords: methods of human capital evaluation, loyalty, workaholism, value generator, devaluator. Introduction Both loyalty and workaholism are terms referring to the qualitative value of human capital – individual and team capital as well as the whole organization. Quality, on the other hand, determines human capital value which can be understood in a variety of ways (among others, as the replacement, strategic or market value). It is assumed that the way loyalty influences that value is different from the way workaholism affects it, i.e. loyalty is its generator, and workaholism its devaluator. The aim of the article is to verify the assumption on the basis of critical analysis and reference books as well as to deal with the following research issue: What are the similarities and differences between loyalty and workaholism in selected human capital evaluation methods and can one identify the methods which would be more and less useful to determine generators as well as devaluators of human capital? 26 LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… In the first section of the paper the state of research on loyalty and workaholism as the features that constitute the quality of human capital were presented. The evolution and the current stage of development of human capital valuation methods were also presented in this section. 1. The state of research on loyalty and workaholism as determinants of human capital quality Loyalty and workaholism are not the only determinants of the human capital quality. However, these days they seem to be of great significance. Employee loyalty can be described as “the (perceived) probability of work continuance in an organization by an employee with greater or lesser commitment – and certain emotional attachment towards the organization regardless of its image on the market – thanks to employee`s or other staff`s well-being or due to lack of other opportunities to find a different job or high costs of changing the employer“ (Lipka, 2012, p. 20). Such a definition of loyalty reflects the following types (singled out according to such inner mechanisms as trust, habit, commitment): − partnership loyalty (there is trust, habit and positive organizational commitment), − commitment loyalty (there is trust and positive commitment), but it does not reflect the types of loyalty with no commitment, i.e. − loyalty of convenience (there is trust and habit), − conscious loyalty (there is only trust), − loyalty out of habit (there is only habit). It does not reflect those types of loyalty where employees` commitment is of negative nature (e.g. employees sabotage the company`s operations), i.e. − lenient loyalty (there is also trust and habit), − conditional loyalty (there is no habit, but there is trust), − helpless coercion loyalty (there is no trust, but there is habit), − unaccepted coercion loyalty (there is no trust or habit). The above definition refers to the most desired types of loyalty from the organization`s perspective. One should keep in mind that commitment, differentiating those types (apart from trust and habit), includes: − affective commitment, − continuance commitment, − normative commitment (Meyer, Allen, 1991, pp. 67-69). 27 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS Partnership and commitment loyalty (and to a lesser degree loyalty of convenience, conscious loyalty and loyalty out of habit), especially that of indivisible and long-term nature, can be a behavioural boost to the human capital value as well as to the organisation itself for the following reasons: − the influence on employment stability (so difficult to achieve in times of increased competition, lack of MVEs and battling to get the best personnel, even intensified by demographics and changing values), which helps increase company profitability (Reichheld, Teal, 2007, p. 159), − smaller loss of customers (and its implications, e.g. increased turnover) (Gerpott, Paukert, 2011), which is of greater significance to services where tacit knowledge is vital (Schüller, Fuchs, 2005, p. 29), − loyalty effect (Schüller, Fuchs 2005, p. 189), i.e. good performance after a longer period of employment (gaining experience), − better work quality (the same reasons as in loyalty effect), − smaller costs for training courses, − greater resistance to marketing activities of competitive businesses among persons representing the above types of loyalty, and greater tolerance to lack of pay rise or even reduced salaries (Buchanan, Gilles, 1990), − good opinions and referrals contributing to the company`s human capital and clientele, − cost reduction relating to turnover and training programmes, − high staff morale despite witnessing (disloyal) employees leave, − the viability of planning, − cost reduction relating to controlling (Šmid, 2003, p. 141), − lack of limitations in applying the latest management methods (e.g. High Performance Work Systems). All in all, loyalty: − affects attitudes and values (loyalty itself can be labelled as good attitude or conduct), − prevents the loss of knowledge, aptitude and skills, − contributes to company`s healthy relationships, − improves motivation, i.e. improves all the components of human capital. Workaholism, the other qualitative feature of human capital, is described as “obsessive commitment which is characterized by high employee`s ambitions, inability to control habits in the workplace, and too much work (work dedication) connected with lack of the individual`s activity in other areas of life, which 28 LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… results in the deterioration of employee`s well-being and dysfunctional interpersonal relationships (Wojdyło, 2010, s. 18). This syndrome is considered a type of addiction (Oates, 1971), which in opposition to other addictions is socially approved and it is even associated with high job performance. Workaholism is also described in terms of behavioural aspect (it is represented by A behaviour, which is characterized by fast pace of life, taking up extremely difficult tasks and setting high standards), affective aspect (job satisfaction), cognitive aspect (automatic thinking, fixed opinions and assumptions concerning work), attitudes towards work (overzealous) or compulsive-obsessive personality (perfectionism, exaggerated thoroughness, rigidity, inability to delegate work). All the above factors foster excessive involvement in a working life. The main symptoms of workaholism include: − inner obligation to work with no outer coercion (inability to `cut off` from work and not to think about it), − recognizing work as the core of one`s life, which determines its purpose and establishes it as the main value as well as one`s identity and self-esteem, − loss of control over one`s life in a working environment due to excessive involvement in one`s work and setting too high, often unrealistic standards (“lost in work”), − working life takes over other areas of one`s life (lack of other activities, working time is extended to leisure), − erratic behavior which results from applying defensive mechanisms (among others, ignoring the problem, rationalising longer working hours, compensating all kinds of emotional deficiencies, denying bad effects of work addiction), − inability to “abstain” from work without some negative consequences, such as self-destructive thoughts and emotions (constant thinking about work, stress, guilt complex, anxiety) (Lipka, Waszczak, Winnicka-Wejs, 2013). The definition of workaholism and its symptoms imply that it is a syndrome and a problem determined by personality, entailing negative consequences for an individual, their family as well as for an organisation. However, is the abovementioned opinion on workaholism not one-sided (too clinical an approach) and radical? According to some researchers, such as Machlowitz, “workaholism is an employee`s commitment to career life”, “workaholics are passionate about their work” and therefore “the organisation reaps benefits employing such workers” (Golińska, 2011, p. 12). If one considers a broader context, including work as a priority in a value hierarchy and work ethics, then workaholism seems to be a natural consequence of high expectations from the family, working environment and society towards an individual. 29 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS One of such expectations is conscientiousness, which in Five Factor Theory by Costa Jr. and McCrae constitutes a dimension of distinctive features – one of five personality dimensions (apart from neuroticism, openness to experience, extraversion and agreeableness). Those factors include six components, describing the aspects of a given factor in detail. When it comes to conscientiousness, its components are as follows: competence, propensity for tidiness, obedience, an aim for achievements, self-discipline and prudence – qualities which are very appreciated in employees. Conscientious individuals being dutiful and disciplined as well as ambitious and industrious, become workaholics at some point` (McCrae, Costa, 2005, p. 65). But only conscientiousness taking the form of compulsion/obsession with work – shown in diagnostic criteria ICD-10 and DSM-IV-TR as exaggerated experiencing of doubts, rigidity and perseverance, focusing on details, perfectionism interrupting tasks completion – poses a problem to an organisation because it badly affects its functioning and the quality of human capital. Therefore conscientiousness may lead to workaholism, but not necessarily – it depends, to a great degree, on the management style and the ability to take advantage of human potential, company culture and the situation on the job market. The consequences of workaholism are multidimensional. The following implications can be singled out here: personal well-being, the implications for workaholic`s social environment and risks for an organisation relating to employing workaholics. Workaholism affects all the components of human capital in terms of its value depreciation. And so, excessive involvement in a working life can badly affect knowledge, impairing individual`s memory, perception and focus as well as cognitive structures, including thought activation, hyperactivity of intellectual processes, escapism, reduced intellectual activity (Kalinowski et al., 2005, pp. 117-119). Accompanying anxiety may lead to certain losses (emotional atrophy) and a loss of certain skills, such as a skill of communicating clearly, a loss of empathy and sympathy (Killinger, 2007, pp. 111-153). Constant working typical of workaholism makes a human body function at full stretch at the cost of good health and well-being. The reduction of human capital value in this area may lead to bad health consequences and erratic behaviour – noticeable or inconspicuous (cf. Meissner, 2005, p. 49, after: Städele, 2008, p. 46). Workaholism can result in concentration problems, physical and psychological disorders, overtiredness, which can even lead to total depreciation of human capital (in the case of karoshi – an employee dies of overworking). Decreased value also concerns motivation. It is known that 30 LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… workaholics are driven by inner coercion. Their motivation for work is determined by, first of all, a hidden motivation for their ego protection and selfesteem or gaining recognition from their colleagues (Porter, 1996, pp. 70-84). Workaholism also has an effect on employees` attitudes towards the ways of performing tasks and their relationships with co-workers. Perfectionism as setting too high standards and rejecting imperfect solutions can make it impossible to take full advantage of certain attributes of human capital in an organisation. If work becomes a paramount value (it becomes “god”), work-life balance might be upset, which, in turn, affects a person`s functioning in various spheres of life. It seems, therefore, that the direction of the impact of workaholism is different from that of loyalty. The quoted examples of lowering the value of all the components of human capital seem to indicate that workaholism can be described as a devaluator of human capital value. To state that it is essential to use human capital valuation methods. These methods are – to an extent which is larger than ever before (cf. Table 1) – in the center of researchers’ interest due to the fact that they are treated as a component of business entities valuation – a component which is difficult to measure, but necessary to take into account, since without it a situation depicted as phase 6 (cf. Table 1) occurs. HR specialists and managers have to take into account a possibility of using the results of human capital evaluation in personnel controlling. If an organization uses the strategy of maximizing human capital value, and generally, the idea of value management, one has to keep in mind that certain measurement means, e.g. those concerning loyalty and workaholism must be generally accepted. Table 1. The evolution stages of human capital evaluation methods Stages – Period 1 mid 60s, 20th c 2 mid 60s – beginning of 70s, 20th c 3 beginning of 70s – mid 70s, 20th c 4 mid 70s – beginning of 80s, 20th c 5 80s, 20th c 6 beginning of 90s, 20th c until the present day Description of the stage Theory of human capital and the psychology of an organization The development of the methods based on historical and replacement costs; Brummet, Flamholtz and Pyle introduce the notion of Human Resource Accounting Fist applications of the designed methods in companies Fewer researches, more combined methods, which leads to a decreased number of specialists for applying the methods Fierce competition between US and Japan leads to a greater interest in the field and greater significance of an employee in business operations; lack of solutions to the problems relating to the existing methods New wave of a greater interest due to the increasing role of human capital and the existing value gap; change of market-to-book ratio Source: Based on: Gebauer (2005, pp. 18-230); Dudycz (2005, p. 216); Lipka, Król, Waszczak, Satoła (2008, p. 13). 31 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS The choice of valuation methods must have regard to organization strategies and boundaries, also methodical ones, to their applicability. In the previous study (Lipka, Król, Waszczak, Satoła, 2008) it was found that methodology issues connected with determining human capital value depend on: − lack of justified assumptions and gaps in descriptions of research methodology, − difficulties with establishing the basis for determining the value and assuming research method (the basis is understood as individual or team or human capital as a whole organization; omitting or taking into consideration so-called contextual factors relating to human capital management, i.e. the strategy, structure, company culture), − problems referring to measuring the variables/ways of acquiring data (including economic as well as psychological and organizational data), − difficulties of temporal nature (depreciation of human capital, changeability of the value generated by human capital in time: using historical and/or prospective data with the aid of the methods: a need to take advantage of future values in reference to the present ones), − feedback problems: human resources management – human capital evaluation (narrowed down to the efficiency evaluation of HR practices), − issues referring to the economic situation and management trends (e.g. increasing variety of human capital in an organization, flexibility, the application of lean management and work-life balance and downward movement programmes). 2. Hypothesis and testing procedure The following hypothesis was formulated for the research problem specified in the introduction: H1: The methods of human capital evaluation differ in terms of loyalty and workaholism, which shows that some of them are less and others are more useful to specify given generators and devaluators of human capital. In the study, selected evaluation methods were included, belonging in the following categories: cost (historical costs method), revenue (discounted revenue stream method), multiplier (Mayo monitor, risk value method), indicator (Balanced Scorecard), mixed (Saarbrücken formula), alternative (personnel portfolio) (some authors take into consideration only the first two categories). Access to the detailed descriptions of these methods and the clarity of algorithms during their application were considered while choosing the methods. 32 LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… To verify the hypothesis by deduction based on critical analysis and reference books, the following sources of presenting evaluation methods were used: Brummet et al. (1968, pp. 221-223), Flamholtz (1975a), Mayo (2001, p. 14), Lipka (2007, p. 22-24), Scholz, Bechtel (2005, p. 32-36), Becker, Huselid, Ulrich (2002, pp. 65-89). The following procedure was assumed: − a description of loyalty and workaholism in terms of their contribution to a qualitative value of human capital and their influence on all the components of human capital, i.e. knowledge, aptitude, skills, health, motivation, attitude, values, − loyalty and workaholism as determinants of human capital value in seven selected evaluation methods, − comparative studies and the selection of the most useful method(s). 3. Loyalty and workaholism in selected methods of human capital evaluation in an organization 3.1. Historical costs method In the most popular cost method – historical costs method (Brummet, Flamholitz, Pyle, 1968) – in its “most updated” version, retention investment costs (i.e. loyalty investment) could be incurred as follows: − hiring – direct costs e.g. offering competitive remuneration as part of diversified personnel marketing, − hiring – indirect costs e.g. loyal MVEs promotion, − training – direct costs e.g. training programmes improving employee loyalty, − training – indirect costs e.g. productivity loss during retention investment. According to this method loyalty gauged by retention time increases human capital value. As far as workaholism is concerned direct hiring costs can be taken into consideration as in the case of loyalty, for example the costs related to hiring a non-workaholic, i.e. a person who can skilfully manage the time and take a rest after work, taking care of their health, knowledge, skills and motivation. Such costs are supposed to prevent or intervene in (reduce the effects of) workaholism. The same objective is ascribed to direct training costs (e.g. costs related to individual coaching enhancing time management), indirect hiring costs (e.g. employee reallocation costs preventing their workaholism) and indirect training costs (e.g. time spent by other workaholics talking to the workaholic employee, during which they fail to perform their duties). According to this method, like in the case of loyalty, the higher the incurred costs, the higher the value of human capital (the obvious flaw here is the assumption that costs reflect value). 33 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS 3.2. The discounted revenue streams This method, devised thirty years ago by Flamholtz (1975a), is being revived these days and it is used in human resources in a number of novel applications. It is strictly connected with the loyalty of employees whose value is determined by loyalty itself and revenues they generate on various positions they hold in an organization. According to this method, even those employees who are loyal with no organizational commitment are valuable provided their work performance is “average” and they are willing to be promoted. The employees who represent conditional loyalty are also valuable if their promotion is a precondition for staying in the company. The method shows that human capital value increases due to efficient retention practices (e.g. better fulfilment of employees` needs, such as authority, group identity or achievement) or a faster career path (when the probability of leaving the company is smaller than the values in Table 2 for u, w, p, s, v when other conditions are stable). Table 2. Employee evaluation changes according to discounted cash flow method – example Initial data Employment date S Position 31.12. 2012 Average employment period of the S employee in the M company: Forcast career path of the S employee 34 Year Possible positions Probability of taking up the position by S (%) 2013 2013 2013 2014 2014 2014 2015 2015 2015 2016 2016 2016 2017 2017 2017 I II III I II III I II III I II III I II III l 0 0 b c 0 k e f g h i j d z 01.01.2009 r. X 7 yrs Probability of leaving the company by S before the end of year (%) u u u w w w p p p s s s v v v LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… table 2 cont. Annual positive cash flow for the position I II III Discount rate Specifications A euro B euro C euro m% Currents incurred costs Expected value (in money units) Annual positive cash flow for the S employee in 2013 Annual cash flow for for the S employee in 2014 (100%-u%) * 100% * A Annual cash flow for for the S employee in 2015 (100%-p%) * (k * A + e * B ) f * C) Annual cash flow for for the S employee in 2016 (100%-s%) * (g * A + h * B + i * C) Annual cash flow for for the S employee in 2017 (100%-v%) * (j * A + d * B + z * C) Total Total of the above: D (100%-w%) * (b * A + c * B) Discounted value (in money units) (100%-u%) * 100% * A [(100%-w%) * (b * A + c * B +: (1 + m: 100) [(100%-p%) * (k * A + e * B ) f * C)] : (1 + m: 100)2 [(100%-s%) * (g * A + h * B + i * C)] : (1 + m: 100)3 [(100%-v%) * (j * A + d * B + l * C)] : (1 + m: 100)4 Total of the above: W The value of for the S employee on 31.12.2012. W Source: Own algebraic generalization based on the accounting example in: Bochniarz, Gugała (2005). Reallocation to higher positions with potentially higher revenue may meet the expectations of some workaholics (e.g. workaholics with impaired focus), whereas some of them might not be satisfied (e.g. compulsive-addicted workaholics or those savouring work). The discounted revenue streams method does not differentiate among revenues brought by different employees following the same career paths. It is assumed that the revenues are the same regardless of the position. So, this method can distort the evaluation of those employees who are workaholics and whose revenue will be higher in the short run, but in the long run it will be lower than the assumed average (due to the above-mentioned somatic, mental and social effects of workaholism). 35 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS 2.3. Mayo Monitor This method uses the so-called individual asset multiplier including aptitude, potential, contribution to value and employee`s values compatibility with company`s values. If loyalty is a value (as in some examples of corporate culture, such as culture of power and role model (Harrison and Handy); process culture (Deal and Kennedy); hierarchy culture (Cameron and Quinn); productive culture (Snyder); harmony culture (Peters); communal culture (Goffee); Eiffel Tower culture (Trompenaars and Woolliams), and the employee represents the most desired types of loyalty, this kind of compatibility is scored the highest (2.0 according to the assumptions of the method). Theoretically, a type of loyalty affects the generated value. The type itself can be treated as a variable referring to aptitude profile. Its changing character can be interpreted in terms of potential (for example, from conditional loyalty to loyalty of convenience, from lenient loyalty to commitment loyalty, from helpless coercion loyalty to loyalty out of habit or from conscious loyalty to partnership loyalty). The above implies that loyalty can be subjected to evaluation with the aid of Mayo Monitor. Can workaholism be subjected to such evaluation? Certainly, a type of workaholism and its intensity (the level of its development) belong in the group of variables describing aptitude profile, that is one of the variables in Mayo Monitor. However, only in some types of corporate culture (e.g. in “aggressive” culture, Krawiec, 2010, p. 47), workaholism is considered a value. According to the assumptions of Mayo Monitor, this type of compatibility should be evaluated higher than incompatibility. As far as contribution to creating a value is concerned, it can be insignificant in the case of a relentless workaholic (because of rigidity while doing a job), bulimic workaholic (working unsystematically), savouring workaholic (“immersed” in details and failing to meet deadlines) or narcissistic controller (unable to work in a team). The issue concerning the factors which determine the possibility of transition between workaholic types is interesting. It seems that apart from personality qualities, there are other vital factors, such as the nature of tasks (among other things, the level of their complexity), the employee`s motivation and preferences (interests, coercion/satisfaction level), employer`s requirements (high performance, time pressure), a stage in the employee`s personal life (age) and career life (career path planning and its progress), and self-awareness (insight into a problem) as well as making the effort to tackle problems connected with workaholism (family pressure and support, professional therapy). 36 LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… 2.4. The risk value method The method was devised a few years ago (Lipka, 2007) and it is constantly being improved. It is assumed that according to a selected analytical and point method of job evaluation, every employee should get a task/position of the highest point value which he is able to successfully perform (or meet given job requirements), having all the necessary skills (aptitude profile). This point value can be exchanged into money units (it is established how much one point is worth). However, this is not the whole procedure because it is thought that there might be specific types of personnel risk when an employee is not able to successfully perform the task even though they have the necessary skills and expertise. In other words, the risk destroys, i.e. reduces human capital value measured by the possibility of successful task completion at a specific difficulty level (criteria such as physical exertion, routine or working conditions, which are not related to job complexity, responsibility or team work, should not be taken into consideration when assessing the difficulty of the task). It seems that devising risk maps for both loyalty and workaholism is feasible (cf. Table 3) as well as determining its level (separately for loyalty and workaholism), for example with the aid of Martin and Heaulme`s equation (1998): j i r= ∑∑ r n i =1 j =1 i ij , j ∑∑ n i =1 j =1 ij ij where: rij – risk value, nij – number of personal risk types in the field with a given value and a matrix where there is a risk level for specific probabilities relating to the occurrence and the volume of effects (in Table 3 loyalty risk is 3.66, and for workaholism risk is 8.80, which means that the risk is high only in the case of workaholism as it exceeds 5.0). 37 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS Table 3. Example map of loyalty and workaholism risks Type of risk related to loyalty (L) and workaholism (W) Quality of methods for diagnosing loyalty types in an organisation (L) Quality of methods for diagnosing workaholic types in an organisation (W) Work efficiency level for workaholics (W) Selection appropriateness of Employee Relationship Management strategy (ERM) (L) Communication skills in team work (W) Quality of method selection for preventing workaholism (W) Quality of method selection for workaholism intervention (P) Employee loyalty scheme profitability (L) Level of loyalty intensity (L) Loyalty types dynamics (L) Probability of occurrence Level of effects Risk value medium medium 4.0 medium medium 4.0 very high high 8.0 high high 7.0 very high high 8.0 medium extreme 7.0 medium extreme 7.0 very low medium low medium low high 1.5 1.8 4.0 So, employee value based on analytical and point job evaluation would be corrected according to risk value. The risk value method includes both loyalty and workaholism, which means it is an all-purpose method. 2.5. The Balanced Scorecard Indicator methods measure the level of goal achievement in specific perspectives. For example, HR Scorecard (Becker, Huselid, Urlich) provides information concerning human capital in terms of basic human resources management tools: recruiting, rewarding, development, retention. This evaluation method comprises both loyalty and workaholism (cf. Table 4). Table 4. HR Scorecard comprising selected aspects of loyalty and workaholism Process Evaluated aspect 1 Cost 38 Recruiting Rewarding Development Retention 2 Cost of shaping working environment fostering new employees` loyalty (L) / Cost of hiring specialists identifying workaholics during recruitment (W) 3 Benefit costs (for loyalty) (L) / Costs of rewarding soft skills` (c.f. 2.6) (W) 4 Costs of employee training in the most desired type of loyalty (L) / Cost of intervention to change a workaholic (W) 5 Cost of employee retention(L) / Cost of investment in work-life programmes (W) LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… table 4 cont. 1 Time Quantity Quality Feedback 2 Time for acquiring loyal (L) / nonworkaholic (W) employees 3 Motivation scheme period to improve loyalty (L) / reduce workaholism (W) 4 Period of time for loyalty stages (L) / workaholism stages (W) Number of rejected jobhoppers in recruitment process (L) / Number of identified workaholics in the process (W) Quality of recruiting loyal employees (L) / non-workaholics (W) Number of employees included in compensation system improving loyalty (L) / reducing workaholism (W) Quality of rewarding loyalty (L) / intervention to prevent workaholism (W) Number of managers included in loyalty coaching programmes (L) / workaholism prevention (W) Managers` satisfaction from acquiring loyal employees (L) / non-workaholics (W) Employees` satisfaction from rewarding their loyalty (L) / from rewarding antiworkaholism (W) Increasing percentage of employees highly assessing loyalty training courses (L) / antiworkaholism courses (P) Differences in retention investments (L) / antiworkaholism (W) 5 Time implementation of employee loyalty scheme (L) / worklife programme (W) Number of employees included in employee loyalty scheme (L) / cognitive therapy to prevent workaholism (W) Quality evaluation of employee loyalty scheme quality (L) / Quality evaluation of behavioral therapy for workaholics (W) Retaining employees` trust included in loyalty schemes (L) / unchanging percentage of workaholic employees suffering from the withdrawal symptoms while at leisure (P) Source: Our own additions to HR Scorecard shown in: Fitz-Enz (2001, p. 115). The method can be used to compare value changes of indicators, yet it does not provide a result relating to human capital value determination. 2.6. Saarbrücken formula a) b) c) d) e) The following parameters are taken into account in the formula: number of full-time employees, market remuneration rate, loss of expertise (determined by the ratio of the industry-determined period of expertise validity and years of service in an organisation), expertise compensation measured by the costs of investment in knowledge development, motivation. 39 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS Loyalty (in the meaning of attitude) is closely connected with motivation. Employees’ job resignations have an impact on the workforce volume, yet only up to a point as the latter depends on the number of the newly recruited employees. Loyalty measured by the years of service in the organisation results in loss of knowledge (thus, there is a different aspect of the connection between loyalty and expertise than the one indicated at the beginning). The remaining parameters do not seem to have any connection with loyalty. Workaholism, in turn, is connected only with motivation. Therefore, the formula encompasses more parameters related to loyalty than workaholism. Most certainly the formula does not measure the loss of human capital value caused by workaholism and/ /or indicate that the value is maintained due to its efficient prevention (e.g. replacement of traditional motivation systems sanctioning workaholism with “soft” criteria-orientated systems, such as customer satisfaction – Poppelreuter, 2007, p. 179). 2.7. Personnel portfolio Personnel portfolio, as opposed to the methods analysed so far, was drawn up with strategic human resources management in mind, however it may also be used for human capital evaluation. By means of the portfolio, it is possible to estimate (unfortunately only approximately, which is a drawback of the method) the share of individual employee segments, e.g. representing particular loyalty intensity (which is gradable) or the degree of workaholism (cf. Figure 1 and 2) among the employees in an organization. Loyalty towards the organisation team Loyalty only towards the team Figure 1. Personnel portfolio of loyalty intensity Z V X Y Divisible loyalty Indivisible loyalty Explanation: the most positive influence on building the value of human capital is depicted by square V. 40 LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… Workoholism – predicted state Figure 2. Personnel portfolio of workaholism degree III A B C II D E F I G H K I II III Workoholism – present state Explanations: Degree I – low. Degree II – medium. Degree III – high. Interpretation: A, D – unfavorable (from the point of view of human capital) workaholism development leading to the decrease in human capital value (with ceteris paribus), B, E, G – stopping the unfavorable dynamics of workaholism – without influence on the dynamics of human capital value (with ceteris paribus), C – the highest and constant workaholism having negative influence on human capital value F, H, K – achieving the effect of a converted workaholic – influence on the increase of human capital value (with ceteris paribus). The method enables grasping the dynamics of different loyalty types or workaholics. Thus, it indicates their rising or falling share in individual segments of intra-organizational labor market. Distinguishing these segments may be helpful in optimizing the process of increasing human capital value. The following categories may be distinguished during the process of increasing the value in connection with shaping loyalty within the ERM (Employee Relationship Management) strategy: I. Most Valuable Employees, II. Most Growable Employees, III. Below Zero Employees, due to the fact that “not all internal clients will be satisfied with the same products and personal services” (Stotz, 2007, p. 32). In personal marketing particular attention needs 41 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS to be paid to the first of the segments – which is a value generator. Otherwise (even in a situation of a surplus of labour supply over labour demand, because it concerns persons who do not have problems finding a new job), the likelihood of job resignations will grow higher and an increase in human capital value will not take place. In the case of workaholism, transitions are also possible, e.g. from a committed workaholic to a workaholic who limits their commitment to work, which may be depicted by means of a portfolio. The size of segments used for indicating changes in the share of particular types of workaholics may be determined via such methods as Work-BAT scale by Spence and Robbins, WART by Robinson and Philips, SZAP by Golińska, KOP Hornowska and Paluchowski or UWES by Schaufeli and Bakker (Szpitalak 2012, pp. 73-79; Golińska, 2008, pp. 54-67). It must be emphasized that these segments may be determined in a quantitative aspect (percentages of employees who belong to them), which opens up the possibility of comparisons and evaluations – even monetary ones. Conclusions Critical analysis and evaluation of reference books showed that human capital evaluation methods vary with respect to the possibility of including value generators connected with loyalty and devaluators connected with workaholism. In the seven selected evaluation methods, basing on the following groups: cost, revenue, multiplier, indicator, mixed and alternative, it was identified to what degree the determinants of human capital value such as loyalty and workaholism were taken into account and the suitability of the methods was evaluated (cf. Table 5). Table 5. Selected methods of human capital evaluation of/ in an organization and an inclusion of loyalty and workaholism in them Name of the method 1 historical costs method (R.L. Brummet, E.G. Flamholtz, C.P. Pyle) discounted revenue streams method (E.G. Flamholtz) 42 Loyalty Degree/taken Evaluation into account of suitability 2 3 Workaholism Degree/taken Evaluation into account of suitability 4 5 yes, indirectly low yes, indirectly low yes, directly medium yes, indirectly medium LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… table 5 cont. 1 Mayo monitor, (A. Mayo) risk value method (A. Lipka) 2 yes, indirectly yes, directly (when the map of personnel risk includes loyalty) HR Balanced Scorecard (B.B. Becker, M.A. Huselid, D. Urlich) Saarbrücken formula (Ch. Scholz, V. Stein, R. Bechtel) personnel portfolio (G.S. Odiorne) 3 4 5 high yes, indirectly high high yes, directly (when the map of personnel risk includes workaholism) high yes, directly (when it includes indicators concerning employee loyalty) medium yes, directly (when it includes the indicator of workoholics medium yes, directly in selected parameters medium yes, directly in one parameter low high yes, directly (when it includes the degree of employees’ workaholism) high yes, directly (when it includes the degree of employee loyalty) Evaluation basis The degree to which the determinant was considered: a) directly (the selected determinant is included in the formula, there is connection with loyalty or workaholism, b) indirectly (the selected determinant is not included in the formula; specification is required in relations to the selected component of evaluation; there is lack of close connection with loyalty or workaholism). Suitability evaluation: − low (due to false methodological assumptions; there is lack of formula measuring the increase in or loss of human capital value), − medium (distortion of the evaluation due to lack of diversification between revenues brought by a variety of loyal/ workaholic employee types; difficulty in delivering the result in the form of specified human capital value), − high (easiness in determining human capital value). 43 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS Table 5 shows that loyalty is included directly in as many as five analysed methods and workaholism in four of them. Most of the methods takes into account both loyalty and workaholism, thus indicating their universal nature. However, the suitability for including particular generators and devaluators of human capital varies to a large extent. The least suitable method turned out to be the historical costs method whereas the highest suitability value was awarded to the monitor Mayo method, risk value method and personnel portfolio method. The remaining methods present a medium level of suitability for the determination of human capital value taking into account loyalty/workaholism. As part of further research on these issues different typologies of workaholism and loyalty could be taken into account. The hypothesis formulated and verified in the article could be tested by being applied to other generators and devaluators of human capital, such as different aspects of attitudes towards working time. References Becker B.E., Huselid M.A., Ulrich D. (2002): Karta wyników zarządzania zasobami ludzkimi. Oficyna Ekonomiczna, Kraków. Bochniarz P., Gugała K. (2005): Budowanie i pomiar kapitału ludzkiego w firmie. Poltext, Warszawa. Brummet R.L., Flamholtz E.G., Pyle. C.P. (1968): Human Resource Accounting: A Tool to Increase Managerial Effectiviness. “Management Accounting”, Vol. 50. Buchanan, Gilles (1990): Value Manager Relationship: The Key to Customer Retention and Profit-Ability. “European Management Journal”, Vol. 8, No. 4. Dudycz T. (2005): Zarządzanie wartością przedsiębiorstwa. PWE, Warszawa. Fitz-Enz J. (2001): Rentowność inwestycji w kapitał ludzki. Oficyna Ekonomiczna, Kraków. Flamholtz E.G. (1975a): Assessing the Validity of Selected Surrogate Measures of Human Resource Value - A Field Study. “Personnel Review” Summer, pp. 37-50. Flamholtz E.G. (1975b): The Metaphysics of Human Resource Accounting and Its Implications for Managerial Accounting. “Accounting Forum”, December, pp. 51- 61. Flamholtz E.G. (1985): Human Resource Accounting. Advances in Concepts, Methods and Applications. Jossey-Bass, San Francisco. Gebauer M. (2005): Unternehmensbewertung auf der Basis von Humankapital. Josef Eul Verlag, Lohmar-Köln. Gerpott T.J., Paukert M. (2011): Der Zusammenhang zwischen Mitarbeiter- und Kundenzufriedenheit: Eine Metaanalyse. „Zeitschrift für Personalforschung“, J. 25. 44 LOYALTY AND WORKAHOLISM IN THE METHODS… Golińska L. (2008): Pracoholizm. Uzależnienie czy pasja? Wydawnictwo Difin, Warszawa. Golińska L. (2011): Pracoholik a pracoholik entuzjastyczny – dwa światy? Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Łódzkiego, Łodź. Kalinowski M., Czuma I., Kuć M., Kulik A. (2005): Praca. Uzależnienia. Fakty i Mity. Wydawnictwo KUL, Lublin. Killinger B. (2007): Pracoholicy. Szkoła przetrwania. Dom Wydawniczy Rebis, Warszawa. Krawiec F. (2010): Kultura biznesu firmy. Szkoła Wyższa im. Bogdana Jańskiego, Warszawa. Lipka A. (2007): W poszukiwaniu metody wyceny kapitału ludzkiego. In: Ed. A. Lipka, S. Waszczak: Zarządzanie wartością kapitału ludzkiego. Wydawnictwo Akademii Ekonomicznej, Katowice. Lipka A. (2012): Pojęcie i ekonomiczna wartość lojalności pracowników. In: Ed. A. Lipka, A. Winnicka-Wejs, J. Acedański: Lojalność pracownicza. Od diagnozy typów lojalności pracowników do Zarządzania relacjami z pracownikami (Employee Relationship Management). Wydawnictwo Difin, Warszawa. Lipka A., Król M., Waszczak S., Satoła M. (2008): Wartościowanie kapitału ludzkiego organizacji (problemy metodyczne i próby ich rozwiązywania). Wydawnictwo Akademii Ekonomicznej, Katowice. Lipka A., Waszczak S., Winnicka-Wejs A. (2013): Aktywność twórcza a pracoholizm. Jak utrzymać kapitał kreatywności pracowników? Wydawnictwo Difin, Warszawa. Martin J.E., Heaulme P.-F. (1998): Risk Management: Techniques for Managing Project Risk. Field Guide to Project Management. Van Nostrand Reinhold, New York. Mayo A. (2001): The Human Value of the Enterprise. Valuing People as Assets: Monitoring, Measuring, Managing. Nivcholas Brealey Publishing, London. Mcrae R.R., Costa P.T. Jr (2005): Osobowość człowieka dorosłego. Perspektywa teorii pięcioczynnikowej. Wydawnictwo WAM, Kraków. Meissner U.E. (2005): Die „Droge” Arbeit: Unternehmen als „Dealer“ und als Risikoträger – personalwirtschaftliche Risiken der Arbeitsucht. Peter Lang Verlag, Bern. Meyer J.P., Allen J.N. (1991): A Three Component Conceptualization of Organizational Commitment. „Human resources Management Review“, Vol. 1, No. 1. Oates W. (1971): Confessions of a Workaholic. The Facts about Work Addiction. World, New York. Poppelreuter S. (2007): Arbeitssucht. Psychologie Verlag Union, Weinheim. Porter G. (1996): Organizational Impact of Workaholism: Suggestions for Researching the Negative Outcomes of Excessive Work. “Journal of Occupational Health Psychology”, No. 1. Reichheld F.F., Teal T. (2007): Efekt lojalności. Ukryta siła rozwojowa Twojej firmy. Helion, Gliwice. 45 A NNA L IPKA , STANISŁAW W ASZCZAK , ALICJA W INNICKA -W EJS Scholz Ch., Bechtel R. (2005): Zehn Nutzen der Saarbrücker Formel. „Personalwirtschaft”, Nr 11. Schüler A.M., Fuchs G. (2005): Marketung lojalnościowy. Total Loyalty Marketing. Jak z zadowolonymi klientami i lojalnymi pracownikami osiągnąć sukces firmy. Akademia Sukcesu – HDT Consulting, Warszawa. Šmid W. (2003): Psychologia i socjologia zarządzania. Słownik terminów. Wyższa Szkoła Zarządzania i Marketingu, Sosnowiec. Städele M. (2008): Arbeitssucht und die zwanghafte Persönlichkeitsstörung. Eine theoretische und empirische Auseinandersetzung. VDM Verlag Dr. Muller Aktiengesellschaft, Saarbrücken. Stotz W. (2007): Employee Relationship Management. Der Weg zu engagierten und effizienten Mitarbeitern. Oldenbourg, München-Wien. Szpitalak M. (2012): Wielowymiarowy kwestionariusz oceny pracoholizmu. Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Jagiellońskiego, Kraków. Wojdyło K. (2010): Pracoholizm. Perspektywa poznawcza. Wydawnictwo Difin, Warszawa. 46 Dominika Latusek‐Jurczak Kaja Prystupa‐Rządca Kozminsky University, Poland COLLABORATION AND TRUST-BUILDING IN OPEN INNOVATION COMMUNITY D OMINIKA L ATUSEK -J URCZAK , K AJA P RYSTUPA-R ZĄDCA Abstract Growing popularity of open innovation communities poses various challenges for business practice. One of them is trust, which facilitates social interaction, provides basis for risk-taking and strengthens cooperation. In virtual environment traditional mechanisms of its development are unavailable. However, in many companies using virtual teams trust is created, maintained and capitalized, which provides indication that it may be developed in other ways. In this paper, the authors present a study of work within testing community in computer game industry based on two-year qualitative fieldwork, which may serve as an example of trust emergence in virtual environment. Keywords: open innovation community, trust, virtual teams. Introduction The advancement of the web and mobile communications has led to a globally shifting movement away from business’ brick and mortar team structures to innovative technical teams working with more interactively connected technologies. The growing popularity of open innovation communities is grounded in the idea that “firms can and should use external ideas as well as internal ideas, and internal and external paths to market, as they look to advance their technology” (Chesbrough, Vanhaverbeke, West, eds., 2006). However, the use of open innovation communities poses various challenges for all actors engaged. One of them is trust, which is particularly difficult to create, maintain and repair in virtual environments (Cook, Snijders, Buskens, Cheshire, eds., 2009; Knights, Noble, Vurdubakis, Willmott, 2001). This paper applies a two-year qualitative fieldwork within the computer game industry testing community to develop a newly applied understanding of trust challenges in the open innovation communities. Trust facilitates social interaction, provides basis for risk-taking and strengthens cooperation. Trust is a necessary component of team environments supporting and executing innovation. Traditionally, trust building processes are enabled by mechanisms such as repeated interaction (e.g. ensuing familiarity) and stabilizing third parties (e.g. institutions in various forms). In the context of distributed teams (Bosch-Sijtsema, Fruchter, Vartiainen, Ruohomäki, 2011) and 48 COLLABORATION AND TRUST-BUILDING… cooperation taking place in virtual environments (Cook et al., eds., 2009), these traditional mechanisms are usually unavailable. The open innovation community can be defined as “as a group of unpaid volunteers who work informally, attempt to keep their processes of innovation public and available to any qualified contributor, and seek to distribute their work at no charge” (Flemming and Waguespack, 2007, p. 166). The model gained popularity in knowledge-driven sectors, inter alia through game development companies. Taking into account rapidly changing industry trends and customers’ preferences, the game development market is considered risky business venture, since ultimately the game may not meet customers’ preferences, and such preferences may be more nuanced and difficult to understand across virtually diverse communities (Prato, Feijoo, Nepelski, Bogdanowicz, Simon, 2010). To minimize such risk companies customarily test their products before officially launching them by engaging people from outside of the organization. Game production companies use different strategies of implementing external gamers’ into their projects. They vary in their decision about when to engage the outsiders, from where to acquire them, how to communicate with them, and how they should protect their product legally. The number of game testers in focus groups differs according to the size of the game; however, business practice suggests it not smaller than several dozen. Smaller organizations possessing limited budgets cannot afford to pay for testing, and they often seek volunteer testers. At the same time, for small companies, the need for rigorous testing phase is even more essential; due to limited resources, they depend much more than on the success of each single game than big companies do. This creates an interesting situation where, on the one hand, a company needs to guard its intellectual property since its loss would be equal to the failure of the product. On the other hand, however, the company needs to disclose sensitive information about the game to the group of volunteers who cannot be effectively monitored and controlled.. Prior research indicated that trust is the alternative mean of control in the case when legal or official protection is unavailable. However, the development of trust in virtual environment is more complicated than in traditional circumstances of cooperation. Therefore the aim of this research is to examine the how is trust created, maintained and capitalized on in open innovation communities. The study has exploratory nature as this issue has not been examined at large (Fleming and Waguespack, 2007). In the first section of this article we examine possible sources of trust in case of no prior experience with peers which is the situation common in open 49 D OMINIKA L ATUSEK -J URCZAK , K AJA P RYSTUPA-R ZĄDCA innovation communities. In the empirical part we present the case of Cubicon, the company that engaged the community of gamers in testing of their new product. In the discussion part we use the concept of swift trust to explain the process of trust building in the specific circumstances of the case. 1. Types of trust Trust can be defined as “the willingness of a party to be vulnerable to the actions of another party based on the expectation that the other will perform a particular action important to the trustor, irrespective of the ability to monitor or control that other party” (Mayer, Davis, Schoorman, 1995, p. 712). Trust is usually a product of repeated interaction; it is gained in time through mutual group member experience in collaboration and is supported by stable environments and third parties. But contemporary life has situations where participation and collaboration is required without any prior knowledge of partners (Latusek and Cook, 2012). Existing research indicates three possible sources for trust in situations when previous experience is unavailable: − Stable institutions (Latusek and Cook, 2012), − ‘Generalized trust’ (Sztompka, 1999), − ‘Swift trust’ (Meyerson, Weick, Kramer, 1996). 2. Stable Institutions Networks are a key source of social capital, and they reflect how rich in social capital that the society is (Cook, Hardin, Levi, 2005; Lin, 2001). In complex environments characterized by uncertainty, as are most contemporary societies, exchanges may occur among actors who are able to restrict or limit uncertainty to a level that makes the risk of cooperation acceptable. This security may be provided either by some form of reliable institutional backing when trust is unavailable. In modern societies, where most exchanges are impersonal, institutions play a crucial role (North, 1990). Note that in those settings where trust matters most (under high uncertainty and obvious risk) individuals are least likely to rely on trust and most likely to require more formal mechanisms of coordination and control (Cook, Rice, Gerbasi, 2004). ‘Reliability’, however, does not equate to requirement of trustworthiness, and we know that partners may be reliable due to institutional forces 50 COLLABORATION AND TRUST-BUILDING… (Cook et al., 2005). Supporting this claim empirically, Yamagishi, Cook, Watabe (1998) experimentally separated assurance relations from trusting relations. It is important to remember that those institutions may lead to more secure and cooperative behavior, they may not automatically produce trust (e.g. Latusek and Cook, 2012; Sitkin and Roth, 1993; Yang, 2007). 3. Generalized Trust People exhibit different levels of trust; some of people are more trusting, and some are less trusting (Fink and Kessler, 2010; Fukuyama, 1995; Putnam, 1993; Putnam, 2000; Yamagishi and Yamagishi, 1994). The propensity to trust which Tanghe Wisse and van der Flier (2010) define as the extent to which people have a general belief in the goodness of human nature is an amalgamation of various factors, but, to a large extent, it is also a culturally learned attitude (Mayer et al., 1995; Tanghe et al., 2010). Cultural attitudes emerge from accumulation of collective experiences shared by groups of people; in other words, they are a product of history (Sztompka, 1999). As part of collective framework of perception and interpretation, trust governs individuals’ behavior. In Poland, the level of ‘generalized trust’ is comparatively low (Gerbasi and Latusek, 2012). Such research finding of this is explained usually through the country’s history (Sztompka, 1999). Today, Poland is still transitioning out of its time under communist rule, even though it has been 20 years from the start of transformation. The socialist state fostered a culture of suspicion and hostility, and the little social capital that remained after decades of life under Soviet domination was subsequently destroyed by transformation to a capitalist state of the early 1990’s. Under the socialist state, there was a strong reliance on closed networks of trust. Individuals accomplished many everyday tasks outside of the state system through networks of trusted associates (Marin, 2002). The uncertainty that accompanied the transition away from socialist rule reinforced this reliance on interpersonal bonds, which provided security and continuity. While closed networks, such as a person’s relationship with their family members, provided a safety net during times of change and uncertainty, an individual’s reliance on these networks had negative consequences; this created a base for corruption and cronyism (Peev, 2002; Rose-Ackerman, 2001a; Rose-Ackerman, 2001b). The patterns of social life formed under Soviet domination turned out to be a two-folded problem, because, in one way, distrust towards the state and reliance on personal connections was a useful defense against oppression and 51 D OMINIKA L ATUSEK -J URCZAK , K AJA P RYSTUPA-R ZĄDCA provided shelter from totalitarian control. In comparison, it also did not contribute to building a more open society (Baier, 1986; Cook and Gerbasi, 2009; Hardin, 2002; Meyerson et al., 1996; Williamson, 1993) 4. Swift trust In an environment where traditional way of trust emergence is hindered by time restraints or limited interaction between actors (e.g. temporary groups), researchers have proposed a notion of ‘swift trust’ (Meyerson et al., 1996). It is portrayed as a unique form of collective group members’ perception and relating that is capable of managing issues of vulnerability, uncertainty, risk and expectations’ (Meyerson et al., 1996). ‘Swift trust’ emerges in circumstances where there is limited pool of possible coworkers, which increases the speed of diffusion of information about each performance; in turn, this makes an individual’s reputation more vulnerable. For instance, freelancers, who being part of an industry-specific network, are very vulnerable to others’ opinions because it may affect their future employment possibilities. Moreover, a contractor’s reputation, for instance team leader, plays an important role in the team development and acceptance process as he or she is entrusted with selection of team members (Kawin, 1992). In other words, team members presume that their engagement in a project was measured on conscious criteria. Task-related work enhances role-based interaction and emergence of more stable and standardized expectations based upon terms of task and specialties (Meyerson et al., 1996). Moreover, cooperation in such circumstances ensures more interactions that are frequent and provide immediate experience with another partner. If there was a possibility of many immediate disappointments in cooperation after this experience, a more rapid development of trust or distrust would be expected (Gambetta, 1988). ‘Swift trust’ will appear in situations where uncertainty is high and unacceptable, and there are premises showing trustworthiness, as social situations provide a cultural expectation of good will rather than ill will (Meyerson et al., 1996). To reduce uncertainty, people rely on predisposition, categorical assumptions and implicit theories to move them toward the greater certainty of trust or distrust (McKnight, Cummings, Chervany, 1998). Moreover, ‘swift trust’ emerges in situations where the risk of disappointment is smaller than the value of advantages associated with taking this risk 52 COLLABORATION AND TRUST-BUILDING… 5. Method The aim of this research was to discover how trust develops in open innovation community. The research question was exploratory in nature, as mechanisms of trust development in such environment were not examined in prior research. For this purpose, the authors used qualitative approach based on grounded theory (Glaser and Strauss, 1957; Konecki, 2000). According to this methodology, the development of theory is the derivative of empirical data analysis, which directly refers to observed reality. The nature of the research question that examines social process induced the author’s decision to use qualitative analysis. The authors decided to choose Cubicon case for several reasons. First, it describes the development of product which was later recognized by the public as one of the best games worldwide of in its’ niche. Second, it serves as example of successful virtual collaboration. Third, Cubicon embodies common ambitions of many indie developers a group of friends with ambitious goal to manage small development studio and design worldwide-known games. As the method of qualitative analysis, the authors followed a case study approach (Yin, 2003). The basic techniques of data collection were semi-structured interviews, a company blog, and an online forum. The interviewees were asked about: game development process, launch and functioning of the community, management of critical situations in the project and reactions of other members, premises of trust development towards others, and risk associated with cooperation. Blogs are particularly useful in qualitative research as they allow researchers to examine social processes over the time, having insight into everyday life of the team members (Hookway, 2008). Whereas, online forum was a rich source of evidence of community members interactions. The interviews were conducted in the period of April-June 2012 with all employees of the company; the documents used in the analysis were from the period 20.11.2006-29.07.2012, consisting of around 450 pages of documentation. Data was coded and analyzed with qualitative research software Dedoose. To maintain credibility of the results, the authors used the data triangulation method. The identities of the interviewees in the text are coded according to the agreement between the researchers and the organization under its study. 6. The case Cubicon was a small game development company with four full-time contractors based in Poland. A young Polish game designer Greg Grudzinski and his 53 D OMINIKA L ATUSEK -J URCZAK , K AJA P RYSTUPA-R ZĄDCA previous coworker, graphic designer, Lena Czerwona, launched it in 2011. The rest of the small team worked from a distance. Uwe Andreassen, a Norwegian programmer who became acquainted with Greg through an online community devoted to Wizzardy. They already had a chance to work on one project. The other specialist hired, Bob Eastman, was a British music composer who also worked earlier with Greg and maintained contact with him through community. The founder, Greg, himself was an experienced game designer who worked both for small and big Polish companies, starting his professional carrier at the age of 16. The company focused on development of games from the niche genre called visual novel, targeting the segment of well-educated women of the age 20-35. Despite being experienced in game development, the team disposed limited knowledge about this particular genre. However, the decision to enter the segment was based on several premises. Namely, visual novels had lower production cost and were developed quicker than other games, such as, for example, RPG*, the demand exceeded supply, and the team would be able to present their unique graphic skills. The team fought to compensate the lack of knowledge and experience by conducting market research through reading different forums, blogs and playing games. Because of the investigation results, they developed project called The Snow White. Not having enough experience in visual novels, Greg decided to engage a gamers’ community to test the project. 7. Motivations to engage Cubicon’s online gaming community Greg started active participation in the gamers’ community when he was 10 years old. He was not only playing games, but also commenting others work. He admired people who non-professionally developed games. Finally, Greg decided to give himself a chance and designed small RPG game, Wizzardy. In similar vein as other developers he consulted it with the gamers’ community. Finally, he published the game on his own website and launched forum, in order to receive more feedback. Online forum, where the game was discussed, was not only a place for bug reporting, but also served as a general discussion about Wizzardy and other interesting games. Some of forum members volunteered for beta testing. Among them was Uwe, who had dual motivation in helping. * 54 RPG – role-playing game, where the gamers takes the role of a character in fictional setting. COLLABORATION AND TRUST-BUILDING… “I was fascinated with that game, but it had many bugs. I wanted to see a better version of it. […] That time I planned to develop my own game. Beta-testing seemed good opportunity to get useful experience”. (Uwe) Uwe respected Greg for the effort and courage that he presented by improving his game. Meanwhile, Greg started his professional career at the biggest Polish game company as a game tester. The company presented a completely different strategy towards knowledge sharing than he had been accustomed to in his online Cubicon’s gaming community. His new employer also organized beta testing sessions before each product launch. However, the procedure looked different than he experienced earlier. Testers were invited to a big conference room; they could not leave the room unsupervised before the official end of game beta testing. Moreover, the company introduced various procedures to secure confidentiality and intellectual property of their products. Greg did not appreciate this approach and decided that he would have never followed such methods. When Greg decided to start his own business, he was sure about engagement of the gamers’ community in the project. The online community gathered around his earlier production was a ready-made solution. 8. Members of the Cubicon’s community forum The forum was opened for everyone interested in Greg’s productions. The primary condition permitting access to discussion was registration, which required electronic submission of a nickname, surname, and email address. The profile was verified through email confirmation. The demo version of the game was available for all after it was published on website of the company. However, the access to more advanced versions was restricted to those community members who expressed interested in testing. The finished game was not available online, but it was transmitted to each person individually via email. Participants of the forum were from different countries, backgrounds and professions (Table 1). Membership included gamers as well as small game producers of various experience levels and industries. As the forum was primary dedicated to a genre of RPG games, the fans of visual novels started to join gradually. Information about the new visual novel production was spreading through various online communities. Individuals fascinated with this genre and actively participating in online communities were a rather small group where most members knew each other through online interactions. 55 D OMINIKA L ATUSEK -J URCZAK , K AJA P RYSTUPA-R ZĄDCA Table 1. Resume of bios of some community members Participant A B C D E F G H I J Description Game producer with 12 years of experience in the industry; journalist of one of the biggest international game portals; winner of East Design Contest 23-years old biology student; fan of RGP and visual novels living in U.S. California 23-years old American studying Japanese linguistic in Japan; fan of visual novels 18 year old American; started playing RPG games; presently fan of visual novels 20- years old; lives in the East of U.S.; poetry lover Australian who finished programming at the university; tried to develop games on his own 22-years old British programmer from big international game development company Norwegian consultant; afterhours game developer 16 years old American, developing games since the age of 10 Teacher of mathematics form Louisiana As on most of online forums, Greg introduced a post calculator that enabled track frequency of each member’s participation in discussion. The number of posts written on the forum was deciding about the rank of each participant. Thus, testers could easily determine the engagement of others participating in discussions of community. Moreover, being active on the forum allowed to build reputation among gamers. 9. Rules of the community Greg did not impose any rules by himself to community operation. At the very early beginning of forum existence, one of the community members posted general rules of behavior, which were standard requirements in the virtual environment. “These are the general forum rules: no spamming, no insulting, no bad words, no flaming don't go off-topic in topics, no nudity, no other bad things you can think of that they're bad. Please follow these rules and everything will be fine”. (A, posted on 29.03.2007) Rules were not violated by the community members. Interestingly, the topic presenting the rules had been viewed only 2596 times (data from December 2012) which made it one of the least popular topics broadcasted by forum members. While working on The Snow White, Greg maintained a style of interaction on the forum as when he was working on Wizzardy, leaving space not only for his project. Often, as a seasoned game developer, he served as a mentor providing development advice and assistance. He kept his responses as immediate as possible, to 56 COLLABORATION AND TRUST-BUILDING… maintain trust, and in cases of prolonged silence, always apologized. Open for criticism, Greg answered all questions and discussed reasoning of his decisions. “Hey, sorry for a bit late reply to this. Major thanks for the feedback. Posts like this are very useful for me as a developer. I can't promise I'll fix everything in The Snow White (I'll try though) (…) [responses to propositions –AUT]: 3) This is actually a technical limitation resulting from how the scene system was made. The game is able to rewind only within the current scenario (a mini segment of a scene). I know it can be a problem and I'll try to find a solution for it eventually. It's something that is more likely to happen in the future project, though. 4) Okay, I can add that. It's a bit more complex, so I'm not sure if I'll do it in The Snow White or in the next game” (Greg, posted 11.07.2012) In his opinion, any advice required comment since individuals devoted their time to prepare it. Following such principles required great effort from Greg; sometimes, he barely had time to implement recommended corrections. Greg tried to compensate from vague community support by sharing details of the game development and releasing upgraded versions. He discussed personalities of the characters and possible scenarios, as those were aspects of the community gamers’ interest. Participating in the decision-making process engaged community members even more in the game. 10. Findings For many game producers, the knowledge about product details is guarded by security systems. Employees are obliged not to disclose information about ongoing projects. Nevertheless, some small firms as Cubicon consciously take the opposite strategy and share their project with a wide range of people by engaging gamers’ communities in testing from the very beginning of production process. Yet, a company risks loss of their product. As discussed in prior sections, the company possesses little control over the behavior of community members. The relation between the company and community is based on mutual risk and trust bets. The risk that Greg took was quite immense. Seasoned community members could have easily stolen, copied, or illegally distributed his game idea. Although, formally, his intellectual rights were secured, within the legal jurisdiction system in Poland, potential misconduct of one of testers would most probably have gone 57 D OMINIKA L ATUSEK -J URCZAK , K AJA P RYSTUPA-R ZĄDCA unpunished. Greg’s forum for discussion about The Snow White enabled him to receive many helpful suggestions from the testing community. Moreover, he compensated his lack of knowledge about the visual novel niche through community members who provided him with segment preferences. As a result, the game won awards in various game contests and gained popularity among online gaming players. Moreover, Greg gained valuable information about marketing activities available for indie developers, like his company, Cubicon, and the methods of negotiation within different publishers. Thus, he was able to plan the promotion and effective development of the game, and he modified the overall company strategy more efficiently. Community members entrusted Greg with their time and online reputations. Some of them even financially contributed to the game by pre-ordering his game and paying online. When the company started lacking financial resources, they believed that Greg would finish the project, and their contribution would not be wasted. Their trust was put to the test a few times due to the often changing the project deadlines. “Do you still plan to release the Snow White? As a customer, which purchased the pre-order, i start to worry”. (online forum member, 12.04.2012) When some of the forum members started to ask whether the game was going to be published, Greg devoted a lot of attention to such posts and tried to explain the delays. “We’re very sorry that the development takes longer that it was planned. […] We try to make good game, and we are stuck with correcting it […] the money that you gave us allowed to pay electricity bills in November”. (Greg posted on 12.04.2012) In addition Greg started to publish on the company’s blog the descriptions of the project progress and more screens from the game. He also was transparent with the money he received providing financial information on how he spent the donations. 11. Discussion As the case indicates, in the open innovation community that we studied, the traditional mechanisms facilitating trust building were missing. The fieldwork, however, indicates that trust indeed existed between members of the online gaming community, and the collaboration resulted in the successful launch of the product, a visual novel named The Snow White. In this concluding section of the paper, we would like to describe how elements from three concepts related to trust building were creatively used by 58 COLLABORATION AND TRUST-BUILDING… community. First, as far as institutions are concerned, the issue of reputation in online interactions should be discussed. People participating in the forum had risked their reputations online and offline, as they willingly disclosed their identities and made tangible contribution to the development of the game. Moreover, through participation in the forum, they built their recognition and credibility among other gamers occupying the niche (Jemielniak, 2013). The process was time-consuming as the registration on the forum required no confirmed credentials, which in prior research were indicated as a condition of effectiveness of social activities (Johnson, 1997). The recognition in the community is important from the point of creating an expert position, but also, it provides insight into possibilities of future cooperation within a team, such as in the case with Uwe and Bob. Second, considering “generalized trust”, the phenomenon of choosing environments that are collaboration friendly, where the available context, (in the case: Poland) is characterized by a low-level of generalized trust (Gerbasi and Latusek, 2012). Transfer of interactions to virtual reality and international composition of the group allowed the online community to overcome difficulties associated with the national cultural framework. Finally, “swift trust” interactions within the community we studied were focused on a role-task approach, which reinforced the professionalization processes within the group (Meyerson et al., 1996). Specific behaviors displayed by Greg and his online Cubicon gaming forum collaborators included keeping short-term promises, applying quick response time to messages between members, and having a goal-orientation motivation bring to mind the tools facilitating the emergence of “swift trust” within the online gaming community. This research brought interesting insight to the debate about necessity of development of interpersonal trust in online communities. While some authors (Jones and Bowie, 1998; O’Leary, Orlikowski, Yates, 2002) underline its’ significance other researchers (Jemielniak, 2013) claim that in may be substituted by bureaucratized procedures. The Cubicon case indicates that trust may be formed as a mixture of institutional measures and norms ruling the cooperation of open innovation community. Presented study has some limitations. The chosen method of inquiry, i.e. qualitative approach based on single case study method, does not allow for statistical generalization of the results. Therefore there should be conducted more elaborated research that would operationalize the presented model of trust development in open innovation communities and verify it on a larger population. Moreover, authors following this research method should be careful with pre- 59 D OMINIKA L ATUSEK -J URCZAK , K AJA P RYSTUPA-R ZĄDCA senting recommendations for practitioners as the obtained results may be context sensitive. Therefore, researcher should supply readers with dense description (Lincoln and Guba, 2009), in order to allow them to measure the degree of transferability of findings into particular context. Nevertheless, the result of this comprehensive literature review and analysis will help future virtual team leaders and gaming founders fully understand respond to the leadership challenges of trust and communication in open innovation communities, further opening expansive networks of connective solutions that encourage an inspire innovation. Acknowledgements: The project was financed from the funds of National Center of Science upon decisions no DEC- 2011/01/N/HS4/04414. References Baier A. (1986): Trust and Antitrust. “Ethics”, Vol. 96, No. 2. Bosch-Sijtsema P.M., Fruchter R., Vartiainen M.,Virpi Ruohomäki V. (2011): A Framework to Analyze Knowledge Work in Distributed Teams. “Group & Organization Management”, Vol. 36, No. 3. Chesbrough H., Vanhaverbeke W., West J., eds. (2006): Open Innovation: Researching a New Paradigm. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Cook K., Gerbasi A. (2009): Trust: Explanations of Social Action and Implications for Social Structure. In: Eds. P. Bearman, P. Hedstrom: The Oxford Handbook of Analytical Sociology. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Cook K., Hardin R., Levi M. (2005): Cooperation Without Trust? Russell Sage Foundation, New York. Cook K., Rice E.R.W., Gerbasi A. (2004): The Emergence of Trust Networks under Uncertainty: The Case of Transitional Economies-Insights form Social Psychological Research. In: Eds. J. Kornai, B. Rothstein, S. Rose-Ackerman: Creating Social Trust in Post-Socialist Transition. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. Cook K., Snijders C., Buskens V., Cheshire C., eds. (2009): eTrust. Russell Sage Foundation, New York. Fink M., Kessler A. (2010): Cooperation, Trust and Performance-Empirical Results from Three Countries. “British Journal of Management”, Vol. 21, No. 2. Fleming L., Waguespack D.M. (2007): Brokerage, Boundary Spanning, and Leadership in Open Innovation Communities, “Organization Science”, Vol. 18, No. 2. 60 COLLABORATION AND TRUST-BUILDING… Fukuyama F. (1995): Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. Free Press, New York. Gambetta D. (1988) Can we trust trust? In: Ed. D. Gambetta: Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relationships. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Gerbasi A., Latusek D. (2012): Cultural Differences in Trust in High-Tech International Business Ventures: The Case of a US-Poland Cooperation. In: B. Glaser, A. Strauss (1957): Discovery of Grounded Theory: Strategies for Qualitative Research. Aldine, Chicago. Hardin R. (2002): Trust and Trustworthiness. Russell Sage Foundation, New York. Hookway N. (2008): Entering the blogosphere: Some Strategies for Using Blogs in Social Research. “Qualitative Research”, Vol. 8 No. 1. Jemielniak D. (2013): Życie wirtualnych dzikich. Poltext, Warszawa. Jemielniak D., Marks A., eds. (2012): Managing Dynamic Technology-Oriented Businesses: High-Tech Organizations and Workplaces. IGI Global, Hershey, PA. Johnson D.G. (1997): Ethics Online. “Communications of the ACM”, Vol. 40, No. 1. Jones T.M., Bowie N.E. (1998): Moral Hazards on the Road to the" Virtual" Corporation.”Business Ethics Quarterly”, Vol. 8, No. 2. Kawin B.F. (1992): How Movies Work. University of California Press, Berkeley. Knights D., Noble F., Vurdubakis T., Willmott H. (2001): Chasing Shadows: Control, Virtuality and the Production of Trust. “Organization Studies”, Vol. 22, No. 2. Konecki K. (2000): Studia z metodologii badań jakościowych. Teoria ugruntowania. Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN, Warszawa. Latusek D., Cook, K.S. (2012).Trust in Transitions. “Kyklos”, Vol. 65 (4), pp. 512-525. Lin N. (2001): Social Capital: A Theory of Social Structure and Action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Lincoln Y.S., Guba E.G. (2009): The Only Generalization is: There is No Generalization. In: Eds. R. Gomm, G.O. Hammersley, P. Foster: Case Study Method. 6th ed. Sage Publications, London. Marin D. (2002): Trust Versus Illusion: What is Driving Demonetization in the Former Soviet Union? “Economics of Transition”, No. 10. Matzat U. (2010): Reducing Problems of Sociability in Online Communities: Integrating Online Communication with Offline Interaction. “American Behavioral Scientist”, Vol. 53, No. 8. Mayer R.C., Davis J.H., Schoorman F.D. (1995): An Integrative Model of Organizational Trust. “Academy of Management Review”, Vol. 20, No. 3. McKnight D.H., Cummings L.L., Chervany N.L. (1998): Initial Trust Formation in New Organizational Relationships. “Academy of Management Review”, No. 23. 61 D OMINIKA L ATUSEK -J URCZAK , K AJA P RYSTUPA-R ZĄDCA Meyerson D., Weick K.E., Kramer R.M. (1996): Swift Trust in Temporary Groups. In: Eds. R.M. Kramer, T.R Tyler: Trust in Organizations: Frontiers of Theory and Research. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks. North D.C. (1990): Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. O'Leary M., Orlikowski W., Yates J. (2002): Distributed Work Over the Centuries: Trust and Control in the Hudson's Bay Company. In: Eds. P.J. Hinds, S. Kiesler: Distributed work. MIT Press, Cambridge. Peev E. (2002): Ownership and Control Structures in Transition to 'Crony' Capitalism: The Case of Bulgaria. “Eastern European Economics”, Vol. 40, No. 5. Prato G.D., Feijoo C., Nepelski D., Bogdanowicz M., Simon J.P. (2010): Born Digital/Grown Digital: Assessing the Future Competitiveness of the EU Video Games Software Industry (No. EUR 24555 EN). Institute for Prospective Technological Studies, Luxemburg. Putnam R. (2000): Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. Touchstone, New York. Putnam R.D. (1993): Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton University Press, Princeton. Rose-Ackerman S. (2001a): Trust and Honesty in Post-Socialist Societies. “Kyklos”, Vol. 54, No. 2-3. Rose-Ackerman, S. (2001b): Trust, Honesty and Corruption: Reflection on the StateBuilding Process. “European Journal of Sociology”, Vol. 42, No. 3. Sitkin S.B., Roth N.L. (1993): Explaining the Limited Effectiveness of Legalistic "Remedies" for Trust/Distrust. “Organization Science”, Vol. 4, No. 3. Sztompka P. (1999): Trust: A Sociological Theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Tanghe J., Wisse B., van der Flier H. (2010): The Role of Group Member Affect in the Relationship Between Trust and Cooperation. “British Journal of Management”, Vol. 21, No. 2. Williamson O.E. (1993): Calculativeness, Trust, and Economic Organization. “Journal of Law and Economics”, Vol. 36, No. 1. Yamagishi T., Cook K.S., Watabe M. (1998): Uncertainty, Trust, and Commitment Formation in the United States and Japan. “American Journal of Sociology”, Vol. 104, No. 1. Yamagishi T., Yamagishi M. (1994): Trust and Commitment in the United States and Japan. “Motivation and Emotion”, Vol. 18, No. 2. Yang T.-H. (2007): Social Factors, Transaction Costs and Industrial Organization. “International Sociology”, Vol. 22, No. 4. Yin R.K. (2003): Case Study Research. Design and Methods. Sage Publication, Thousand Oaks – London – New Delhi. 62 Frédéric Le Roy University of Montpellier 1 and Groupe Sup de Co Montpellier Famara Hyacinthe Sanou University of Montpellier 1 – ISEM DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE? AN EMPIRICAL STUDY IN MOBILE PHONE INDUSTRY F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU Abstract A central question about coopetition is its impact on performance. Past researches on this question obtained mixed results. No past researches have attempted to evaluate the impact of coopetitive strategies on performance compared with other strategies vis-à-vis competitors: aggressive, cooperative or coexistence strategies. In addition, there have been few studies that attempt to establish a relationship between coopetitive strategy and market performance. In order to fill these gaps, this research studies the impact of coopetitive strategy on market performance, compared to the impact of aggressive, cooperative and coexistence strategies. An empirical study is conducted in the mobile telephony industry. The method is a structured content analysis that identifies the strategic movements of mobile operators from different countries and geographical regions. The results show, first, that only three strategies may be identified in the industry: aggressive, cooperative and coopetitive. The results show, second, that the market performance depends on the strategy adopted toward competitors. A coopetition strategy seems to perform better than either an aggressive or a cooperative strategy. An aggressive strategy is more effective than a cooperative strategy. Keywords: aggressiveness, cooperation, coopetition, market performance, mobile telephony industry. Introduction Since the seminal book of Brandenburger and Nalebuff (1996), coopetition has been the subject of an increasing amount of research in the field of strategic management. Researches on coopetition have been developed in many directions, to the point that today it is difficult to make a complete synthesis (Yami et al., 2010; Bengtsson and Kock, 2014; Czakon et al., 2014). An essential question asked about coopetition is that of its impact on performance. From the beginning, coopetition theory has been resolutely normative. For Brandenburger and Nalebuff (1996), coopetition is a strategy that will lead to better performance. This normative point of view has not been questioned and is always considered as relevant in coopetition theory (Bengtsson and Kock, 2014; Czakon et al., 2014). Some past researches are dedicated to establish empirically a relationship between coopetition strategies and performance. In this way, some first studies 64 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… highlight the impact of alliance between competitors on economic and financial performance (Luo et al., 2007; Ritala et al., 2008; Oum et al., 2004; Kim and Parkhe, 2009). Other studies attempt to show the impact of cooperation among competitors on innovation (Belderbos et al., 2004, Neyens et al., 2010; Nieto and Santamaria, 2007; Peng et al., 2011). Latest studies directly use the concept of coopetition to attempt to establish its impact on economic performance (Marques et al., 2009; Morris et al., 2007), on innovation (Quintana-Carcias and BenaviedsVelasco, 2004; Le Roy et al., forthcoming) or on market performance (Ritala, 2012). Researches which study the link between coopetition strategy and performances are however far from exhausting the subject. They do not identify the impact of coopetition strategies on performance compared with the impact of other strategies. The supposed superiority of coopetition strategies over other strategies, like aggressive strategy or cooperative strategy, has therefore never been tested empirically. It is also noteworthy, except Ritala (2012), that none of this research addresses the impact of coopetition on market performance. In the original definition of Brandenburger and Nalebuff (1996), coopetition is supposed to allow rivals to increase the overall value they create for the customer, which should enable them to develop their sales. But just one empirical study is dedicated to this central point of coopetition theory (Ritala, 2012). The present research therefore aims to fill this double gap, by trying to establish empirically the impact of coopetition strategy on market performance, and by comparing it with the impact of cooperative and aggressive strategies. To this end, this research analyzes the strategies implemented by firms in the sector of mobile telephony. The method used is structured content analysis. This method makes it possible to identify the strategic movements of mobile operators from different countries and geographic regions. The results show that mobile operators adopt different strategies in the same industry, deciding to follow an aggressive strategy, a cooperative strategy or a coopetitive strategy. There is also the possibility that firms might adopt a strategy that we describe as the coexistence strategy, where show neither a strong tendency to cooperate, nor a strong tendency to aggression. However, in our sample there appear to be no firms that adopt this strategy. The results also show that the market performance of a firm depends on the strategy it adopts toward its competitors. A coopetitive strategy appears to perform better than either an aggressive strategy or a cooperative strategy. An aggressive strategy appears to perform better than a cooperative strategy. The results obtained in this research contribute significantly to the literature on coopetition. This is the first study comparing the relative impact of aggres- 65 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU sive, cooperative and coopetitive strategies on market performance. It is the first time that these three strategies have been clearly identified in a sector of activity. It is also the first time that the superiority of coopetitive strategy over the other two strategies has been shown empirically. Finally, this research shows that an aggressive strategy is the second best strategy, while a cooperative strategy appears less effective for market performance. 1. Theoretical background Coopetitive Strategies Coopetition theory was first formulated by Brandenburger and Nalebuff in the mid-1990s (Brandenburger and Nalebuff, 1996). Authors use game theory to propose a first model of coopetition centered on the “value network”. Coopetition appears when two rival actors decide to cooperate together to create value for customers. Coopetition is a reconciliation of interests between “complementors” who cooperate while remaining competitors. In this way of thinking, coopetition is “a dyadic and paradoxical relationship that emerges when two companies cooperate in some activities, and at the same time compete with each other in other activities” (Bengtsson and Kock, 1999). The idea of cooperating while remaining competitive is a break from the dominant conception (Yami et al., 2010; Czakon et al., 2014; Fernandez et al., 2014). In this dominant conception, competition and cooperation are seen as opposites, implying that as competition increases, cooperation decreases, and vice versa. The concept of coopetition introduces a cognitive revolution in which cooperation and competition can occur simultaneously between actors who become partner-adversaries, in other words coopetitors. The simultaneity of competition and cooperation is thus the foundation of the concept of coopetition (Czakon et al., 2014; Fernandez et al., 2014). This new conception and its implications have been initially developed by Lado et al. (1997), although, paradoxically, these authors did not use the term of coopetition. Lado et al. (1997) observe that more and more companies are combining aggressive and cooperative strategies. They rely on game theory, the Resource Based View and social network theory to show that, although competition and cooperation have been previously regarded as opposite ends of a continuum, they must now been understood as two independent dimensions. So firms could choice their cooperative orientation, high or low, independently from their com- 66 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… petitive orientation, also high or low. In the same way, for Luo (2007), firms could choice independently to maintain or not a strong competition with rivals and to maintain or not a strong cooperation with these rivals. The recognition of this independence between competition and cooperation is fundamental because it leads to the idea that a company can have four types of strategies (Table 1). It could decide to be aggressive toward its competitors while limiting cooperation with them. This strategy is called “competitive rent seeking behavior” by Lado et al. (1997) and “contending situation” by Luo (2007). We called here this strategy “aggressive strategy”. Conversely, the company could decide to be less aggressive as possible with its competitors while cooperating strongly with them. This strategy is called “collaborative rent seeking behavior” by Lado et al. (1997) and “partnering situation” by Luo (2007). We call this strategy “cooperative strategy”. The company may also decide to be as less aggressive and as less cooperative as possible with its competitors. This strategy is called “monopolistic rent seeking behavior” by Lado et al. (1997) and “isolating situation” by Luo (2007). We call this strategy “coexistence strategy”. Finally, the company may choose to be very aggressive toward its competitors while cooperating also strongly with them. This strategy is called “syncretic rent seeking behavior” by Lado et al. (1997) and “adapting situation” by Luo (2007). We call this strategy “coopetitive strategy”. Table 1. Strategies vis-à-vis competitors Propensity to aggressiveness low high high cooperative strategy coopetitive strategy low coexistence strategy aggressive strategy Propensity to cooperation Sources: Adapted from Lado et al. (1997) and Luo (2007). The concept of propensity to aggressiveness has its roots in competitive dynamic researches (Smith et al., 1992; Young et al., 1996; Ferrier et al., 1999; Ferrier, 2001; Ferrier et al., 2002; Offstein and Gnyawali, 2005). This school of thought considers competition from a behavioral point of view. Strategy is defined as a set of competitive actions and reactions. The competitive aggressiveness of a company is a multidimensional concept that is defined as the propensity of the company to proactively and intensively initiate competitive actions and 67 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU respond quickly to competitive actions of its rivals (Ferrier et al., 2002). According to competitive dynamic researches, a company will be considered as having a high propensity to aggressiveness if it initiates many competitive actions, more varied and faster than competitors, and respond rapidly to competitive actions initiated by competitors (Ferrier, 2001). The concept of propensity to cooperation has its roots in networks researches (Granovetter, 1985; Burt, 1992; Miles and Snow, 1992; Nohria, 1992; Baum and Dutton, 1996; Gulati et al., 2000). According to Granovetter (1985), Thorelli (1986) or even Jarillo (1988), firms are considered as part of a network of relationships that influence their behavior. The network itself refers to two or more organizations involved in cooperative relationships (Thorelli, 1986). This network provides a number of resources and allows the company to develop its own stock of resources and skills. The position in the network is considered as the key element that determines the resources and expertise that the company can control. This position is expressed in the form of centrality within the network. According to Faust (1997), centrality is defined as the ability to be active in a network, or “degree centrality”, the capacity to intermediate the flow of resources between actors, or “betweenness centrality”, or the ability to be in relationships with other actors who are themselves central, or “eigenvector centrality”. According to network researches, a company will be considered as having a high propensity to cooperation if occupy a central position in the network by multiplying formal and informal exchanges with competitors. Once defined propensity of aggressiveness and propensity to cooperation it’s possible to define aggressive, cooperative, coexistence and coopetitive strategies. 1. The aggressive strategy consists in having a high propensity to aggressiveness and a low propensity to cooperation. In this strategy firms 1) initiate many competitive actions, more varied and faster than competitors, and respond rapidly to competitive actions initiated by competitors while 2) not occupying a central position in the network and minimizing formal and informal exchanges. 2. The cooperative strategy consists in having a low propensity to aggressiveness and a high propensity to cooperation. In this strategy 1) firms initiate competitive actions on fewer occasions, with less variety and less rapidly than competitors while 2) occupying a central position in the network by multiplying formal and informal exchanges with competitors. 3. The coexistence strategy consists in having a low propensity to aggressiveness and a low propensity to cooperation. In this strategy 1) firms initiate 68 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… competitive actions on fewer occasions, with less variety and less rapidly than competitors while 2) not occupying a central position in the network and minimizing formal and informal exchanges. 4. The coopetitive strategy consists in having a high propensity to aggressiveness and a high propensity to cooperation. In this strategy firms 1) initiate many competitive actions, more varied and faster than competitors, and respond rapidly to competitive actions initiated by competitors 2) while occupying a central position in the network and increasing formal and informal exchanges with competitors. In our framework, aggressive strategies, cooperative strategies, coexistence strategies and coopetitive strategies are conceptually distinct. However, there was no empirical study that determines if these strategies are significantly different in an industry. In line with theories of coopetition, we assume that the coopetitive strategy is a specific strategy, distinct from aggressive, cooperative and coexistence strategies. We formulate, thus, the following hypothesis: Hypothesis 1: Coopetitive strategy is a strategy significantly distinct from aggressive, cooperative and coexistence strategies. 2. Coopetitive strategy and performance The pioneering researches on coopetition consider that this strategy should become an alternative to strategies based on pure cooperation and strategies based on pure competition. Brandenburger and Nalebuff (1996), Lado et al. (1997) and Bengtsson and Kock (1999, 2000) agree that coopetition is a strategy that holds the greatest potential for firms’ performance or, at least, has the greatest impact on variables clearly identified as likely to make them more efficient. Cost savings, sharing of resources and stimulation that promote innovation are among the potential gains from this strategy. A company that follows a coopetitive strategy is in a position where it can benefit from the advantages of both competition and cooperation. Competition pushes firms to introduce new product combinations, to innovate, to improve products-services, and so on. It is therefore a progressive factor for companies. In addition, it enables companies to improve their market position and their performance at the expense of rivals (Lado et al., 1997). Cooperation, in turn, allows the company to have access to almost-free resources, skills and knowledge that are necessary or indispensable (Lado et al., 1997). 69 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU Coopetition is therefore intended, in its foundations, as a normative theory which promises superior performance to the companies that adopt it as a strategy. This fundamental assertion of the theory of coopetition has resulted in some empirical verification. Several studies attempt to determine the impact of strategies of alliances between competitors on economic and financial performance (Luo et al., 2007; Ritala et al., 2008; Oum et al., 2004; Kim and Parkhe, 2009). Other studies try to determine the impact of cooperation between competitors on innovation performance (Belderbos et al., 2004, Neyens et al., 2010; Nieto and Santamaria, 2007; Peng et al., 2011; Le Roy et al., forthcoming). Last past researches directly use the concept of coopetition to attempt to establish its impact on economic performance (Marques et al., 2009; Morris et al., 2007), on innovation (Quintana-Carcias and Benavieds-Velasco, 2004) and on market performance (Ritala, 2012). Some studies establish a negative relationship between coopetition and performance (Nieto and Santamaria, 2007; Ritala et al., 2008; Kim and Parkhe, 2009). Nieto and Santamaria (2007) show that cooperation with competitors has a negative impact on the newness of innovation. Ritala and colleagues (2008) show that a relatively high number of alliances within a group of competing firms contributes negatively to performance. Kim and Parkhe (2009) show that competing similarity between alliance partners is negatively related to alliance outcomes. Another previous study shows first a negative, then a positive link between cooperation with competitors and innovation performance (Luo et al., 2007). Luo and colleagues, (2007) show that the impact of company alliances with a company’s competitors on performance is curvilinear. Oum et al. (2004) show that horizontal alliances have a positive impact on productivity but not on profitability. Some studies find a negative or positive impact depending contingency variables. Ritala (2012) shows that the relationship between coopetition strategy and market performance is moderated by market uncertainty, network externalities and competitive intensity. Le Roy et al. (forthcoming) found that, for French firms, coopetition strategy has a deep impact on innovation when coopetitors are located in other countries in Europe or in USA, and no impact when coopetitors are located in France. Other researches show a positive relationship between cooperation with competitors and performance (Belderbos et al., 2004; Quintana Carcias and Benavieds-Velasco, 2004; Marques et al., 2009; Morris et al., 2007; Neyens et al., 2010; Peng et al., 2011). Quintana Carcias and Benavieds-Velasco (2004) show that coopetition strategies increase technological diversity and the devel- 70 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… opment of new products. Morris et al. (2007) show that there is a strong and positive relationship between coopetition strategies of SMEs and their performance. Belderbos et al. (2004) show a positive impact of coopetition on labour productivity and the number of sales per employee. Marques and colleagues (2009) show that coopetition between french football clubs does not improve their athletic performance, but does improve their economic performance. Neyens and colleagues (2010) show that there is a positive impact of “continuous strategic alliances” with competitors on the performance of radical innovation. Peng et al. (2011) show that cooperation with competitor leads to better performance. If investigations on the link between coopetition and performances lead to conflicting results, they share two limitations. On the one hand, they do not distinguish the impact of coopetition strategies on performance from the impact of other strategies toward competitors. The assumed superiority of coopetition strategies over pure cooperation and pure competition has never been tested empirically. On the other hand, these studies, at the exception of Ritala (2012), didn’t include market performance. However, in the initial definition of Brandenburger and Nalebuff (1996), coopetition is supposed to allow rivals to increase the overall value they create for customers, which should allow both partners to increase their sales. It is therefore necessary to try to establish empirically the impact of coopetitive strategies on market performance compared with the impact of aggressive, cooperative and coexistence strategies. 3. Coopetitive strategy and market performance One of the key issues raised by research on competitive aggressiveness is that of its impact on performance (Ferrier et al., 1999; Ferrier, 2000). It is argued that a company needs to be more aggressive than its competitors. In this purely competitive vision, only the most aggressive companies can hope to achieve market leadership and maintain their position. The most successful companies are those that have the greatest number of competitive actions; that respond more quickly to competitive actions of their rivals and are more unpredictable in their behavior. Conversely, the least successful are those that introduce the fewest competitive actions, which take more time to respond to competitive actions of their rivals and initiate predictable competitive actions and reactions (Mac Crimmon, 1993; Miller and Chen, 1996; Ferrier et al., 1999; Ferrier, 2001). 71 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU In contrast, researchers on cooperative strategies agree that membership in a network has a significant impact on performance, mainly because the networks create asymmetrical access to resources (Granovetter, 1985; Nohria, 1992; Baum and Dutton, 1996; Gnyawali and Madhavan, 2001). Research suggests that the links between companies help to develop and “absorb” technology (Ahuja, 2000), to withstand environmental and technological shocks (Powell, 1990) and, most importantly, to increase performance (Hagedoorn and Schakenraad, 1994; Singh and Mitchell, 1996; Zaheer and Zaheer, 1997; Baum et al., 2000). For a company, making many alliances in the sector is a source of competitive advantage (Eisenhardt and Schoonhover, 1996; Galaskiewicz and Zaheer, 1999). The company will be more successful because it is involved in cooperative relationships and is located in the heart of cooperative relations that take place in its industry. By being central in the network, that is to say, at the centre of cooperative actions taking place in the industry, the company benefits from more resources than companies that are not central, and consequently they should perform better (Ibarra and Andrews, 1993). Research on aggressive strategies considers that these strategies have a positive impact on performance (Young et al., 1996; Ferrier et al., 1999, Ferrier, 2001; Ferrier et al., 2002; Offstein and Gnyawali, 2005). However, these strategies benefit the company only through the advantages of aggressiveness. Research on cooperative strategies also considers that cooperative strategies have a positive impact on performance (Granovetter, 1985; Nohria, 1992; Baum and Dutton, 1996; Gnyawali and Madhavan, 2001). However, these strategies benefit to the firm only through the advantages of cooperation. Coopetitive strategies combine aggressive and cooperative strategies. A priori, they should therefore allow the company to benefit simultaneously from the advantages of these two strategies. Overall, companies that follow coopetitive strategies should, thus, have better performance than companies that only follow aggressive strategies or cooperative strategies. So we formulate the following hypotheses: Hypothesis 2: Firms that follow coopetitive strategies have better market performance than firms that follow aggressive strategies Hypothesis 3: Firms that follow coopetitive strategies have better market performance than firms that follow cooperative strategies 72 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… 4. Method The mobile operators A mobile operator is a company that provides communications services remotely. It is a company that sells services using telecommunication infrastructures. It can be an independent company or a subsidiary of a constructor of a public company. There are several types of mobile operators. A simple classification contrasts traditional operators, who have telecommunication networks with virtual operators, who use the networks of traditional operators. It is not easy to identify the activity of virtual operators. The study therefore focuses only on traditional operators. Mobile telephony is a rapidly evolving industry, experiencing a spectacular development. The mobile operators industry is also a multi-market industry. Competition in the industry of mobile operators is both localized and globalized. Before 2000, national telecommunications markets were closed to competition and national operators were directly controlled by the state. However, the deregulation of the early 2000s resulted in the entry of new operators into domestic markets. These new operators are either creations ex nihilo or foreign competitors wishing to expand outside their domestic markets. These foreign competitors usually enter national markets by forming alliances with national operators. This situation makes it difficult to understand the relationship of competition in the industry. A narrow vision suggests that all the operators present in a single domestic market should be thought of as competitors. However, this vision does not take into account existing agreements between competitors in the national market, and ignores competitors that are not present on the market. Cooperation provides technology and product innovation for the competitors present in the domestic market. So there is indirect competition through cooperation agreements between operators who are not present on the same national markets. To take into account this specific characteristic of the sector, we have adopted a broad view of competition, considering that all the mobile operators are in situation of potential and indirect competition. Data collection Secondary data are widely used to observe companies’ competitive actions and their cooperative relationships. Here, we mainly use secondary data to detect companies’ strategic actions. As a first step, we conducted four semi-structured interviews with experts in the telecommunications sector and mobile telephony. 73 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU We interviewed four IDATE (Institute of Audio Visual and Telecommunications in Europe) consultants, three consultants who had a thorough knowledge of mobile telephony and telecommunications and the head of studies on telecommunications. This enabled us to establish a list of periodicals that identify all the relevant strategic moves in the sector. Data on strategic actions were obtained from issues of Global Mobile and 3G Mobile or 3GWireless. All the strategic movements which took place in the sector have been identified. About 6,300 pages of documentation were analyzed. Mobile operators considered in the analysis are traditional operators who initiated at least one cooperative and/or competitive action between 2000 and 2005. During this period, the mobile industry experienced major changes with digitization and liberalization in the telecommunications sector. Around the period 2000 to 2005, a series of mergers and acquisitions had a particular impact on the industry. These changes led us to study this industry during this period. We considered the strategic actions of mobile operators, whatever their original focal/domestic market place (Europe, Asia / Pacific, Africa / Middle East, etc.). Indicators on the country and on the measures of performance were obtained from World Telecommunications International Data. Identification of strategic actions A competitive action is a direct external movement, specific and observable, initiated by a firm to enhance its competitive position or defend it (Smith et al., 1991; Smith et al., 1992; Miller and Chen, 1996; Grimm and Smith, 1997). Cooperative action is defined as any type of action that establishes a link between at least two firms and involves exchange, sharing, co-development, and so on (Gulati, 1995). It includes strategic alliances, joint ventures, research and development, national and international roaming agreements, participating in trade associations and technological consortia, and the like. To detect strategic movements, we proceeded by structured and detailed content analysis (Jaugh et al., 1980; Ferrier and Lyon, 2004) of each issue of Global Mobile and 3G Wireless. This method is effective and recommended for exploring the strategic processes of a large multivariate sample (Ginsberg, 1988). In a first step, we developed an annual directory of traditional operators in each country. We then distinguished between the strategic actions of mobile operators and those of their controlling telecom operators. For example, we recorded the competitive actions of Telefonica de Espana and not those of Telefonica, which is its 74 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… controlling telecom operator, who also has a fixed line network, and provides other services. Then we made the distinction between cooperative and competitive actions by searching for keywords in articles (Grimm and Smith, 1997). For instance, “price cut”, the “launch of new service or new product”, have been associated to competitive actions while “roamings’deals”, “joint venture”, “alliances” have been associated to cooperative actions (see appendix for more details). Then, 706 cooperative actions and 2.595 competitive actions, divided between 190 mobile operators, were detected. Competitive actions were classified into six categories of competitive actions in accordance with the classification existing in previous research (Ferrier and Lee, 2002). Regarding cooperative actions, we considered only cooperative actions between two or more mobile operators. Those between a mobile operator and its controlling telecom operator, or with another telecom operator, were ignored. A cooperative action including several operators was recorded as a cooperative action of each of the operators involved (Fjeldstat et al., 2004). For operators who changed names during the period of study, we used the new name of the operator, while recognizing the competitive and cooperative actions that were carried out under the former name. Measurement of variables Aggressive Propensity The measure of the aggressive propensity of the operator includes the three main measures of competitive aggressiveness, namely the volume of competitive actions and reactions, the time it takes between each consecutive competitive action and reaction and the complexity of the competitive actions and reactions. The volume of competitive actions (CONC) of the operator is measured by the number of competitive actions initiated by it during the period of study (Ferrier, Smith and Grimm, 1999) and the number of responses to competitive actions of other operators. Competitive activity of the firm = Σ NT* The time of the competitive actions (TIME) is the average time it takes the firm between two consecutive competitive actions and/or reactions. We calculated it for a given operator by the annual average number of days separating two * Where NTL = number of competitive actions of the firm. 75 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU actions and/or reactions. Actions and reactions were treated as equivalent (Young, Smith and Grimm, 1996). The dates of competitive actions selected are those that were explicitly given in the articles. Where this was not available, we used the date of publication of the journal. When there were two dates for the same competitive action, we selected the earlier. Average time = ∑ (t – t’) / NTL* The complexity of competitive actions (COMPLEX) of the firm is evaluated using the method used by Ferrier and Lee (2002), Ferrier et al. (1999) and Nayyar and Bantel (1994), by a Herfindahl-type index. Complexity = 1 − ∑ ⎛⎜⎜ N a / NT ⎞⎟⎟ 2 L⎠ ⎝ ** A high score indicates that the operator initiates complex sequences of competitive actions while a low score indicates that the competitive actions of the firm varied very little. Cooperative Propensity The cooperative propensity of the firm was calculated by measuring the centrality of each mobile operator in the network of cooperative actions that occurred in the sector. The concept of centrality has several meanings in network analysis. Our concept of centrality is adopted from Faust (1997), which is the most complete. Faust (1997) defines the centrality of an actor as its ability to be active in the network, or “degree centrality”, its ability to intermediate the flow of resources between actors, and its capacity to be in relationship with other actors that are themselves central, or “eigenvector centrality”. Three measures of centrality were identified: “degree centrality” (DC), “betweenness centrality” (BC) and “eigenvector centrality” (EC). The measurements were obtained from 6,178 observations and Ucinet Netdraw 2.069. Degree centrality reflects the direct relational activity of the firm with other members of the network. In this study, it is measured by all the direct links forged by a mobile operator with other mobile operators during the study period. * ** Where t and t’ are the dates of two consecutive competitive actions of the firm and NTL is the total number of competitive actions/reactions of the operator during the year. We first calculated the ratio that represents each type of competitive action as a proportion of all the competitive actions of the firm. Then, to take into account the weight of the distribution of each type of actions initiated (Na), these ratios were squared. Finally, we calculated the sum of the mean squares obtained, which gives us the complexity of the competitive actions of the firm. 76 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… We considered one of the most widely used measure of centrality (that of Freeman, 1979) to capture it. C D = d ( ni ) = X i + = ∑ X ij . j Betweenness centrality reflects the intermediate position occupied by a mobile operator in relationships between several other mobile operators; the ability of the operator acting to facilitate interactions between other operators. The Betweenness centrality of firm (ni) is obtained following Faust (1997) by the equation: C B ( ni ) = ∑ j<k * g jk ( n i ) / g jk . The eigenvector, seeks to highlight the number of direct connections of an operator, as well as the centrality of the operators with whom it has links (Bonacich et al., 2004). Denoting the eigenvector centrality of node ni in a onemode network by CE(ni), eigenvector centrality is expressed as: CE(ni) = CE (nj).xij**. The measurements were obtained from 6,178 observations and Ucinet Netdraw 2.069. After the identification of cooperative actions, we proceeded first to the codification of all operators who participated in at least one cooperative action with another mobile operator during every year from 2000 to 2005. Each mobile * ** With gjk the number of geodesics between nj and nk; gjk (ni) the number of geodesics between nj and nk that contain ni and CB(ni) = the betweenness centrality of firm ni. According to Faust (1997), an intermediate step in calculating betweenness centrality is to find the 'partial betweenness' of nodes in the network (Freeman, 1979). Node ni 's partial betweenness counts the number of pairs of other nodes whose geodesic(s) contain node ni. If there is more than one geodesic between a given pair of nodes, then ni receives fractional credit, where the fraction is reciprocal of the number of geodesics between the pair. Let gjk be the number of geodesics between nj and nk, and let gjk(ni) be the number of geodesics between nj and nk that contain ni. If all geodesics are equally likely, then the probability that a geodesic between nj and nk contains node ni is equal to gjk(ni) / gik.. The betweenness centrality of node ni, denoted by CB(ni), is defined as the sum of these quantities across all pairs of nodes. For a graph with g nodes, CB(ni) reaches its maximum value of (g – 1)(g – 2)/2. when node ni is on geodesics between all other pairs of nodes. According to Faust (1997), the centrality of a node is proportional to the centrality of the nodes to which it is adjacent, weighted by the value of the tie between the nodes. Finding centrality values, CE(ni) that satisfy this equation for all nodes in a graph involves solving a system of simultaneous linear equations. This standard eigenvectoreigenvalue problem is expressed by the equation Xc = λc where X is a g × g sociomatrix, λ is its largest eigenvalue, and c is a vector of centrality scores (the eigenvector corresponding to the largest eigenvalue). 77 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU operator has been assigned a code. We introduced these codes into Ucinet who performed the calculation of the centrality for each operator from the code that had been assigned. Market performance In general, in the mobile industry, data on financial performance are few or not available. In addition, because they derive from very different accounting systems, comparing operators’ financial performances would not make sense. Similarly, measures of market share are not available for all operators. The most common and available measures of market performance are: 1) the number of subscribers of the operator, in thousands or millions of subscribers, and 2) the annual increase in the number of subscribers of the operator, which is obtained by averaging the annual differences in the number of operators during the period of study. Average annual variation in the number of subscribers Number of subscribers Number of subscribers Number of subscribers Data treatment To define groups of strategically similar operators and formalize a typology of strategies in the sector, we conducted a principal components analysis and a K-Means clustering. A nonparametric test of comparison, the Kruskall Wallis’s test, was used to highlight the differences that exist between the performances of operators according to their strategy. The classification into groups of mobile operators according to their strategy was obtained experimentally by two methods conducted concomitantly: a principal component analysis (PCA) and a K-Means clustering. We proceeded by back and forth between the two methods (PCA and K-Means), in order to identify the smallest number of groups of operators constituted in terms of possible elements that might explain the greatest proportion of total variance, while at the same time comprising, for each group, at least 10% of the observations. Because the number of variables varied between two and six, we carried out PCA with two to six components, as well as K-Means Clustering using the same components, focusing on the total variance explained in PCA, and on the number of observations in each class for K-Means clustering. To compare the groups obtained, we opted for a nonparametric comparison test, which does not assume specific probability distribution of the variables. A test of 78 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… normality of distribution (Kolmogorov–Smirnov’s test), indicated that the performance data were not normally distributed and influenced our choice of test. We adopted a Kruskal Wallis’s test, which is a comparison of medians, and is an alternative non-parametric test for analysis of variance (ANOVA), and in particular makes it possible to compare more than two groups simultaneously. We tested the null hypothesis that there were no differences at the level of performance of operators according to the strategy adopted, the alternative hypotheses being the research hypotheses. The results of the factor analysis, K-Means Clustering and the comparison tests are presented and interpreted in the next section. 5. Results Categorization of operators Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics of the variables used and Table 3 presents the correlation matrix of the variables used. The results in Table 4, with a Kaiser–Meyer–Olkin (KMO) index equal to 0.774 (> 0.6) and a significant Barlett’s test of sphericity at 5% (with a value of 0.000), make the method of factor analysis appropriate for treatment of the data. Table 2. Descriptive Statistics Mean 1.64 278.06521627 .8903114200 1.12 33.48696 2.77606 8579383.76 .71 CONC TIME COMPLEX DC BC EC SUBS SUBSINC Standard Error 2.968 131.444623094 .22057832564 2.281 151.622667 9.268697 2.019E7 6.356 N 1140 1125 1107 1138 1140 1139 925 300 Table 3. Correlation matrix 3 4 COMPLEX 5 1 –,735** ,629* ,03 ,040 ,000 ,000 1125 1107 1138 1140 CONC TIME 1 CONC TIME 2 Pearson Correlation Sig. (two–way) N Pearson Correlation 1140 ** –,735 1 –,745 DC BC 6 7 ,513*** ,481** ** –,389 8 9 SUBSIN C 10 ,304* ,331*** ,032** ,000 ,000 ,021 1139 925 300 EC * –,297 SUBS *** –,233 –,290 –,033** 79 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU table 3 cont. 1 2 Sig. (two-way) N COMPLEX Pearson Correlation Sig. (two-way) N DC Pearson Correlation Sig. (two-way) N BC Pearson Correlation Sig. (two-way) N EC Pearson Correlation Sig. (two-way) N SUBS Pearson Correlation Sig. (two-way) N SUBSINC Pearson Correlation Sig. (two-way) N 3 4 5 ,700 ,042 1125 1104 1123 ** ** ,03 1125 * ,629 -,745 ,040 ,700 1107 1104 *** ** 6 1 1107 ** -,389 ,299 ,000 ,042 ,031 1138 1123 1105 ** * ** ,513 ,481 -,297 ,209 ,000 ,076 ,047 7 8 9 10 ,076 ,340 ,000 ,042 1125 1124 910 295 ** ,299 ,209 ,242 ,262 ,013 ,031 ,047 ,530 ,048 ,519 1105 1107 1106 901 293 *** 1 ,721 1138 *** ,721 ** ,733 *** ,347 ,051*** ,000 ,026 ,000 ,001 1138 1137 923 300 * 1 ,481 ,000 *** ,105 ,080 ,000 ,025** ,032 1140 1125 1107 1138 1140 1139 925 300 ,304* -,233 ,242 ,733** ,481* 1 ,099* ,192 ,000 ,340 ,53 ,026 ,080 ,092 ,592 1139 1124 1106 1137 1139 924 299 1 ,029** *** *** ** *** * ,,262 ,000 ,000 ,048 ,000 ,000 ,092 925 910 901 923 925 924 ** ** ,032 -,033 ,013 ,021 ,042 ,519 300 *** *** ,051 001 295 293 300 . P < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, *p < 0.1 ,105 1139 -,290 ,331 ,347 *** ** ,099 ,612 925 ** ,025 ,192 ,029 ,032 ,592 ,612 300 299 300 300 1 300 Table 4. Index KMO and Bartlett's test KMO and Bartlett's Test Kaiser–Meyer–Olkin Measure of Sampling Adequacy Bartlett's Test of Sphericity Approx. Chi-Square df Sig. .774 732.360 15 .000 The PCA presented in Table 5 identifies three groups of mobile operators with at least 10% of the total number of operators in each group and explaining the greatest proportion of variance (88%). This first result allows us to identify three types of strategy toward competitors among companies in the mobile telephony industry. 80 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… Table 5. Total variance explained Initial eigenvalues Component 1 2 3 4 5 6 total 3.507 1.016 .800 .379 .222 7.653E -02 % of variance 58.446 16.929 13.333 6.317 3.699 1.276 cumulative % 58.446 75.375 88.708 95.025 98.724 100.00 0 Extraction sums of squared loadings % of cumulatotal varitive% ance 3.507 58.446 58.446 1.016 16.929 75.375 .800 13.333 88.708 Rotation sums of squared loadings % of cumutotal varilative% ance 3.190 53.163 53.163 1.110 18.499 71.662 1.023 17.046 88.708 Tables 5 and 6 present the results of the K-Means Clustering. Table 6 shows that each group of operators consists of at least 10% of the total number of operators. Table 6 shows the final cluster centres and gives the “profiles” of the three groups of operators. It shows an allocation of operators according to their propensity for cooperation and/or aggressiveness. Table 6. Number of observations in each group 1 2 3 Group 49.000 18.000 120.000 187.000 3.000 Valid Missing Table 7. Final cluster centres Group CONC DC BC EC TIME COMPLEX 1 1 1.566 1 3.8 2160 1 2 3 .875 0 3.2 865 2 3 16 1.975 2 7.8 197 3 The first group is composed of 49 operators (Group 1). These operators are not very aggressive. They have the lowest number of competitive actions and reactions of the three groups (CONC = 1). These are also the operators who take most time to respond to competitive actions of their rivals (TIME = 2160) and initiate the simplest competitive actions and responses (COMPLEX = 1). On the other hand, they obtain relatively high centrality scores (DC = 1566, BC = 1, EC = 3.8) 81 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU compared to the second group of operators (DC = 875, BC = 0, EC = 3.2). The operators of the first group are therefore considered to be operators that follow a cooperative strategy. The second group is composed of 18 operators (Group 2). These operators are more aggressive than the first group. They have a greater number of competitive actions and reactions than those of the first group (CONC = 3). They also initiate more frequently, and have more complex competitive actions and reactions (TIME = 865, COMPLEX = 2) than the first group. Conversely, the operators in the second group are less cooperative than those of the first group. They have measures of centrality (DC = 875, BC = 0, EC = 3.2) that are all lower than those of the first group (DC = 1566, BC = 1, EC = 3.8). Operators in the second group are considered to be the operators that follow an aggressive strategy. The third group consists of 120 operators (Group 3). These operators are more aggressive than those of the first or second groups. They have a greater number of competitive actions and reactions (CONC = 3) than those of the first or second group. They also initiate more frequent (TIME = 197) and more complex (COMPLEX = 3) competitive actions and reactions than the operators in the first and second groups. The operators in the third group are also more cooperative than those in the first and second groups. They have higher centrality scores than the operators in the other two groups (DC = 1.975, BC = 2, EC = 7.8). These operators are both very aggressive and very cooperative. We therefore consider them to be operators adopting a coopetitive strategy operators, according to the definition of coopetition previously adopted. In summary, three strategies have been identified: cooperative strategy which corresponds to Group 1, aggressive strategy corresponding to Group 2 and coopetitive strategy which corresponds to Group 3. Hypothesis 1 can be considered as partially validated. A strategy of coopetition is significantly different from aggressive and cooperative strategies, which are themselves significantly distinct from each another. However, the coexistence strategy has not been identified. Comparison of market performance of the three groups Tables 8 and 9 show that in terms of the number of subscribers and variation of the number of subscribers, the performance of the groups of mobile operators are significantly related to the strategy adopted. In accordance with Hypotheses 2 and 3, the coopetitive operators (i.e. those that are both very aggressive and very cooperative) perform better than simply aggressive operators or simply cooperative operators. These two tables also show the superiority in terms of market performance of aggressive operators compared with cooperative operators. 82 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… Table 8. Strategy and number of subscribers Ranks N 36 14 112 162 Group Cooperative Operators Aggressive Operators Coopetive Operators Total Mean Rank 45.81 51.75 96.69 Test Statistics* 38.222 2 0.000 Chi-squared df Asymp. Sig. * Kruskal Wallis Test; Grouping Variables: Classification (K Means). Table 9. Strategy and number of subscribers Ranks N 35 14 110 159 Group Cooperative Operators Aggressive Operators Coopetive Operators Total Mean Rank 59.89 66.64 88.10 Test Statistics* Chi-squared df Asymp. Sig. * 11.262 2 0.004 Kruskal Wallis Test; Grouping Variables: Classification (K Means). 6. Discussion The aim of this research is to establish a link between coopetition strategies and market performance. In coopetition theory, strategies that consist of simultaneously combining aggressiveness and cooperation are inherently considered superior to purely cooperative or purely aggressive strategies (Bengtsson and Kock, 1999; Brandenburger and Nalebuff, 1996; Lado et al., 1997). However, there is little empirical evidence for this assertion. This research thus evaluates the impact of coopetitive strategies on market performance compared with the impact of aggressive, cooperative and coexistence strategies. The results obtained in this research show, first, that aggressive, cooperative and coopetitive strategies are statistically distinct and correspond to different choices for firms in the sector of mobile telephony. As postulated by coopetition theory, a range of strategic stances toward competitors can be adopted (Lado et al., 83 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU 1997; Luo, 2007). The aggressive and cooperative propensity may well be regarded as independent, which means that firms have to make choices. When choosing the best strategy toward competitors, three main theories disagree. In competitive dynamic theory, firms are considered to perform better if they are aggressive (Ferrier, 2001). In network theory, firms have an interest in searching for a relational advantage (Contractor and Lorange, 1988; Dyer, 1997). In coopetition theory, the most successful firms are those that benefit from both aggressiveness and from cooperation (Brandenburger and Nalebuff, 1996; Lado et al., 1997; Bengtsson and Kock, 1999, 2000). The results of the present study make clear, first, that coopetition strategies are statistically significantly distinct from aggressive and cooperative strategies. The basic postulate of coopetition theory, that a firm can choose whether to be highly aggressive and lowly cooperative, or to be lowly aggressive and highly cooperative, or to be both highly aggressive and cooperative, is validated. The results obtained then make it possible to decide on the best strategy in relation to market performance. The results show that, in terms of number of subscribers and variation in the number of subscribers, the strategy adopted toward competitors has an impact on performance. Coopetition strategies are shown to be better than aggressive and cooperative strategies. This result is original, as there is no comparable previous research. It is the first time that the supposed superiority of coopetitive strategy over aggressive and cooperative strategies has been established statistically. These results do not refute the findings of previous research on aggressive strategies or on cooperative strategies. They simply show that each of these strategies, conducted in opposition with each other, leads to lower levels of performance than strategies that combine them. In this sense, the results confirm previous work, indicating that coopetition is a successful strategy (Belderbos et al., 2004; Quintana Carcias and Benavieds-Velasco, 2004; Marques et al., 2009; Morris et al., 2007; Neyens et al., 2010; Peng et al., 2011; Ritala, 2012; Le Roy et al., forthcoming). The research results should be considered as a confirmation of the validity of coopetition theory as defined by its founders (Brandenburger and Nalebuff, 1996; Lado et al., 1997; Bengtsson and Kock, 1999, 2000). The strategy of being both aggressive and cooperative appears as the most frequent adopted and most profitable for mobile operators. This result is consistent with challenging western ways of thinking, which tend to perceive competitive and cooperative behaviour as two ends of a continuum, rather than as two independent dimensions 84 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… (Lado et al., 1997; Luo, 2007). The results lead to a new conception of strategies toward competitors, which cannot be reduced to a simple choice between competition and cooperation, but is conceived as a complex combination of competition and cooperation. In this complex combination, strategies that combine high levels of aggressiveness and cooperation are the most successful. Another original result obtained in this research is that an aggressive strategy is better than a cooperative strategy. In previous research, the merits of these two strategies have been never been directly compared. Past researches focused on the impact of one or the other, namely on the impact of cooperation or competitive aggressiveness (Gnyawali et al., 2006). We show here that an aggressive strategy performs better than a cooperative strategy. This result points to the success of the theory of competitive dynamics, which recommends firms to adopt an aggressive behavior for better performance (Young et al., 1996; Ferrier et al., 1999; Ferrier, 2001; Ferrier et al., 2002; Offstein and Gnyawali, 2005). Conversely, this result challenges studies that affirm that social networks and embeddedness have a direct and positive impact on performance (Granovetter, 1985; Nohria, 1992; Baum and Dutton, 1996; Gnyawali and Madhavan, 2001). If cooperative strategies appear to be unavoidable in the industry, this strategy should be considered a necessary condition for success rather than a discriminating factor that promotes better market performance. This result can be partly explained by the characteristics of the sector. The mobile industry requires a high level of compatibility between the services and products offered by competing operators. This compatibility is both enforced by legal frameworks and decisive for customers. Competitors must necessarily cooperate with each other to provide this compatibility. Another feature of the industry is that products are combinations of several basic components. The different components belong to separate markets but are highly interdependent. Market players must work together to provide complex products-services to customers. Cooperation is therefore an almost inevitable strategy in the mobile telephony industry. In this context, the difference is created not only by the ability to cooperate more than other operators, but also by the ability to develop an aggressive strategy. An aggressive strategy can be implemented by reducing the necessary cooperation to a minimum and maximizing aggression. This is achieved by operators in Group 2. This strategy then performs better than the strategy that relies only on cooperation in terms of market performance. An aggressive strategy can also be established, not by reducing the cooperative effort, but by increasing it. This is the case of the operators in Group 3, which follow a coopetitive strategy. This strategy performs better than the other two strategies. 85 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU Conclusion Researches on coopetition are more and more common in the field of strategic management (Yami et al., 2010; Bengtsson and Kock, 2014; Czakon et al., 2014). These researches are developed even though the normative aspects of coopetition theory have not been fully confirmed. Past researches highlight the impact of alliance between competitors on economic and financial performance (Luo et al., 2007; Ritala et al., 2008; Oum et al., 2004; Kim and Parkhe, 2009), the impact of cooperation among competitors on innovation (Belderbos et al., 2004, Neyens et al., 2010; Nieto and Santamaria, 2007; Peng et al., 2011; Le Roy et al., forthcoming) and the impact of coopetition on economic performance (Marques et al., 2009; Morris et al., 2007), on innovation (Quintana-Carcias and Benavieds-Velasco, 2004) and on market performance (Ritala, 2012). Among these researches, none compares the effects of coopetition strategies on performance with those of aggressive, cooperative and coexistence strategies. Similarly, none of these researches, except Ritala (2012), deals with market performance. To fill this gap, the present research studies the relative effects of relational strategies toward competitors on market performance. An empirical study is conducted, using secondary data in the mobile telephony industry. This study shows that the three strategies of aggressiveness, cooperation and coopetition are well represented in this industry. No firm was identified that adopted the coexistence strategy. The study also shows that a coopetitive strategy performs better in increasing market share than the other two detected strategies. This result is original and has not been shown previously in the literature. Finally, the study shows that aggressive strategies perform better than cooperative strategies, which is also an original result. The managerial implications of this research are important. They lead to specific recommendations for companies in this industry that aim to increase the number of their subscribers. Indeed, the results lead us to recommend that companies should adopt a strategy that is simultaneously cooperative and aggressive rather than a purely aggressive strategy or a purely cooperative strategy. To increase the number of subscribers, being more active both on the aggressive and on the cooperative front is clearly the best strategy. The second best strategy is an aggressive strategy. Finally, an essentially cooperative strategy is advisable for companies who wish to have a large number of subscribers. These results should be considered in relation to the limitations of the research. One of the major limitations is that the various operators whose perfor- 86 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… mances we are comparing are of very different sizes, and are operating in different geographical areas and different domestic markets, which means they do not necessarily deal with identical environmental situations and conditions of competition. It would therefore, in future research, be better to study the impact of environmental conditions on strategic choices and performance. A second limitation is that we focused in this study on volume measures of performance, because they are the measures of performance of reference in the industry, and the only measures that are completely accessible. This raises the problem of operators that do not adopt strategies of volume, but rather have niche strategies with high added value. This is very often the case with virtual operators. An extension of the research would consist of looking for other measures of performance and consideration of all operators (traditional and virtual). Another limitation is that we have restricted this study to a single industry. This choice has certain advantages, but the results obtained certainly depend partly on the characteristics of the industry. It would therefore be beneficial to undertake similar studies in other industries, to determine if there is invariance in terms of results or if these results can only be observed in the mobile telephony industry. A last limitation concerns the use of the method of analysis, namely structured content analysis based on articles published in journals dedicated to the sector (Smith et al., 1992; Chen et al., 1992; Ferrier, 2001; Gnyawali and Madhavan, 2001). This is a highly specific method that, although it makes it possible to observe the behaviour of firms, has the weakness that it is difficult to replicate, making it difficult to generalize the results. Further research could use a different method of analysis, such as using primary data, to see if similar results can be observed and to establish more precisely the scope of the results of this research. Generally, the results obtained here are as good as those of many contributions to the literature, which require further confirmation and, therefore, argue for further research. Comparing the merits of different strategies to adopt toward competitors is still a relatively unexplored field of research. The relative performance of aggressive, cooperative and coopetitive strategies is not well established. There are probably multiple contingent factors that should be introduced for a better theoretical explanation. Only further research will support these theoretical developments. 87 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU References Ahuja G. (2000): The Duality of Collaboration: Introducing and Opportunities in the Formation of Inter-Firm Linkage. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 21, No. 3. Baum J.A.C, Dutton J.E. (1996): The Embeddedness of Strategy. In: Eds. J.A.C. Baum, J.E. Dutton: Advances in Strategic Management. Vol. 13, JAI Press, Greenwich. Baum J.A.C., Calabrese T., Silverman B.S. (2000): Don't Go it Alone: Alliance Network Composition and Start-ups Performance in Canadian Biotechnology. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 21, No. 3. Belderbos R., Caree M., Lokshin B. (2004): Cooperative R&D and Firm Performance. “Research Policy”, Vol. 33, No. 10. Bengtsson M., Kock S. (1999): Cooperation and Competition in Relationships Between Competitors in Business Networks. “The Journal of Business and Industrial Marketing”, Vol. 14, No. 3. Bengtsson M., Kock S. (2000): Coopetition in Business Networks: to Cooperate and Compete Simultaneously. “Industrial Marketing Management”, Vol. 29, No. 5. Bengtsson M., Kock S. (2014): Coopetition – Quo Vadis? Past Accomplishments and Future Challenges. “Industrial Marketing Management”, Vol. 43, No. 2. Bonacich P., Holdren A.C., Johston M. (2004): Hyper-Edges and Multidimensional Centrality. “Social Networks”, Vol. 26. Brandenburger A., Nalebuff B. (1996): Co-Opetition. Doubleday, New York. Burt R. (1992): Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Chen M-J., MacMillan I. (1992): Nonresponse and Delayed Response to Competitive Moves: The Roles of Competitor Dependence and Action Irreversibility. “Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 35, No. 3. Contractor F.J., Lorange P. (1988): Competition vs. Cooperation: A Benefit/Cost Framework for Choosing Between Fully-Owned Investments and Cooperative Relationships. “Management International Review”, Vol. 28, No. 4. Czakon W., Fernandez A.S., Mina A. (2014): Editorial – From Paradox to Practice: The Rise of Coopetition Strategies. “International Journal of Business Environment”, Vol. 6, No. 1. Dyer J.H. (1997): Effective Inter-firm Collaboration: How Firms Mimic Transaction Costs and Minimize Transaction Value. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 18, No. 7. Eisenhardt K.M., Schoonhover C.B. (1996): Resource Based View of Strategic Alliance Formation: Strategic and Social Effects of Entrepreneurial Firms. “Organization Science”, Vol. 7, No. 2. Faust K. (1997): Centrality in Affiliation Networks. “Social Networks”, Vol. 19, No. 2. 88 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… Fernandez A-S., Le Roy F., Gnyawali D. (2014): Sources and Management of Tension in Coopetition Case Evidence from Telecommunications Satellites Manufacturing in Europe. “Industrial Marketing Management”, Vol. 43, No. 2. Ferrier W. (2000): Playing to Win: the Role of Competitive Disruption and Aggressiveness. In: Eds. R.K. Bresser, M.A. Hitt, R.D. Nixon, D. Heuskel: Winning Strategies in a Deconstructing World. John Wiley and Sons, New York. Ferrier W. (2001): Navigating the Competitive Landscape: The Drivers and Consequences of Competitive Aggressiveness. “Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 44, No. 4. Ferrier W., Peteraf M.A. (2002): Conversation on the Dynamics Context and Consequences of Strategy: Introduction to the Special Issue. “Managerial and Decision Economics”, Vol. 23, No. 5. Ferrier W., Smith K.G., Grimm C. (1999): The Role of Competitive Action in Market Share Erosion and Industry Dethronement: A study of Industry Leaders and Challengers. “Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 42, No. 4. Ferrier W.J., Lee H. (2002): Strategic Aggressiveness, Variation, and Surprise: How the Sequential Pattern of Competitive Rivalry Influences Stock Market Returns. “Journal of Managerial Issues”, Vol. 14, No. 2. Ferrier W.J., Lyon, D.W. (2004): Competitive Repertoire Simplicity and Firm Performance: The moderating Role of TMT Heterogeneity. “Managerial and Decision Economics”, Vol. 25, No. 6-7. Ferrier W.J., Mac Fhionnlavich C., Smith K.G., Grimm C. (2002): The Impact of Performance Distress on Aggressive Competitive Behaviour: A Reconciliation of Conflicting Views. “Managerial and Decision Economics”, Vol. 23, No. 4-5. Fjeldstad Ø.D, Becerra M., Narayanan S. (2004): Strategic Action in Network Industries: An Empirical Analysis of the European Mobile Phone Industry. “Scandinavian Journal of Management”, Vol. 20. Freeman L.C (1979): Centrality in Social Networks: Conceptual Clarification. “Social Networks”, Vol. 1. Galaskiewicz J., Zaheer A. (1999): Networks of Competitive Advantage. “Research in the Sociology of Organizations”, Vol. 16. Ginsberg A. (1988): Measuring and Modelling Changes in Strategy: Theoretical Foundations and Empirical Directions. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 9, No. 6. Gnyawali D.R., He J., Madhavan R. (2006): Impact of Coopetition on Firm Competitive Behaviour: An Empirical Examination. “Journal of Management”, Vol. 32, No. 4. Gnyawali D.R., Madhavan R. (2001): Cooperative Networks and Competitive Dynamics: A Structural Embeddedness Perspective. “Academy of Management Review”, Vol. 26, No. 3. Granovetter M. (1985): Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness. “American Journal of Sociology”, Vol. 91, No. 3. 89 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU Grimm C.M., Smith K.J. (1997): Strategy as Action: Industry Rivalry and Coordination. OH South-Western College Publishing, Cincinnati. Gulati R. (1995): Social Structure and Alliance Formation Patterns: A Longitudinal Analysis. “Administrative Science Quarterly”, Vol. 40, No. 4, pp. 619-653. Gulati R., Nohria N., Zaheer A. (2000): Strategic Networks. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 21, No. 3. Hagedoorn J., Schakenraad J. (1994): The Effect of Strategic Technology Alliances on Company Performance. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 15, No. 4. Ibarra H., Andrews S.B. (1993): Power, Social Influence, and Sense Making: Effects of Network Centrality and Proximity on Employee Perceptions. “Administrative Science Quarterly”, Vol. 38, No. 2. Jarillo J.C. (1988): On Strategic Networks. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 9, No. 1. Jauch L.R., Osborn N.R., Martin T.N. (1980): Structured Content Analysis of Cases: A Complementary Method for Organizational Research. “Academy of Management Review”, Vol. 5, No. 4. Kim J., Parkhe A. (2009): Competing and Cooperating Similarity in Global Strategic Alliances: An Exploratory Examination. “British Journal of Management”, Vol. 20, No. 3. Lado A.A., Boyd N.G., Hanlon S.G. (1997): Competition, Cooperation and the Search for Economic Rents: A Syncretic Model. “Academy of Management Review”, Vol. 22, No. 1. Le Roy F., Robert M., Lasch F. (forthcoming): Choosing the Best Partner for Product Innovation: Talking to the Enemy or to a Friend? “International Studies of Management Organisation”. Luo X, Rindfleisch A., Tse D.K. (2007): Working with Rivals: The Impact of Competitor Alliances on Financial Performance. “Journal of Marketing Research”, Vol. 44, No. 1 Luo Y. (2007): A Coopetition Perspective of Global Competition. “Journal of World Business”, Vol. 42, No. 2. MacCrimmon, K. (1993): Do Firm Strategies Exist? “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 14, Special Iss. Marques P.; Robert F., Le Roy F. (2009): Coopetition Between SMEs: An Empirical Study of French Professional Football. “International Journal of Entrepreneurship & Small Business”, Vol. 8, No. 1. Miles R.E, Snow C.C. (1992): Causes of Failure in Network Organizations. “California Management Review”, Vol. 34, No. 4. Miller D., Chen, M-J. (1996): The Simplicity of Competitive Repertoires: An Empirical Analysis. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 17, No. 6. 90 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… Morris M.H., Koçak A., Alper Ö. (2007): Coopetition as a Small Business Strategy: Implications for Performance. “Journal of Small Business Strategy”, Vol. 19, No. 1. Nalebuff B.J., Brandenburger A.M. (1997): Co-opetition: Competitive and Cooperative Business Strategies for the Digital Economy. “Strategy & Leadership”, Vol. 25, No. 6. Nayyar P.R., Bantel K. (1994): Competitive Agility: A Source of Competition Advantage based on Speed and Variety. “Advances in Strategic Management”, Vol. 10, No. 4. Neyens I., Faems D., Sels L. (2010): The Impact of Continuous and Discontinuous Alliance Strategies on Start-up Innovation Performance. “International Journal of Technology Management”, Vol. 52, No. 3-4. Nieto M. J., Santamarıa L. (2007): The Importance of Diverse Collaborative Networks for the Novelty of Product Innovation. “Technovation”, Vol. 27, No. 6-7. Nohria N. (1992): Is a Network Perspective a Useful way of Studying Organization? In: Eds. N. Nohria and R. Eccles: Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form and Action. Harvard University Press Boston, MA. Offstein E.H., Gnyawalli D.R. (2005): Firm Competitive Behaviour as a determinant of CEO pay: Empirical Evidence from the US pharmaceutical Industry. “Journal of Managerial Psychology”, Vol. 20, No. 5. Oum T. H., Park J.-H., Kim K., Yu C. (2004): The Effect of Horizontal Alliances on Firm Productivity and Profitability: Evidence from the Global Airline Industry. “Journal of Business Research”, Vol. 57, No. 8. Peng T-J.A., Pike S., Yang J. C-H., Roos G. (2011): Is Cooperation with Competitors a Good Idea? An Example in Practice. “British Journal of Management”, Vol. 23, No. 4. Powell W.W. (1990): Neither Market, nor Hierarch: Network Forms. “Annual Series of Analytical Essays and Critical Reviews, Research in Organizational Behaviour”, Vol. 12. Quintana-Carcias C., Benavieds-Velasco C.A. (2004): Cooperation, Competition and Iinnovative Capability: A Panel Data of European Dedicated Biotechnology Firms. “Technovation”, Vol. 24, No. 12. Ritala P. (2012): Coopetition Strategy – When is it Successful? Empirical Evidence on Innovation and Market Performance. “British Journal of Management”, Vol. 23, No. 3. Ritala P., Hallikas J., Sissonen, H. (2008): The Effect of Strategic Alliances between Key Competitors on Firm Performance. “Management Research: The Journal of the Iberoamerican Academy of Management”, Vol. 6, No. 3. Singh K., Mitchell W. (1996): Precarious Collaboration: Business Survival after Partners Shut Down or Form New Partnerships. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 17, Special Iss. Smith K.G., Grimm C.M., Gannon M.J. (1992): Dynamics of Competitive Strategy. Sage, Newsbury Park, CA. 91 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU Smith K.G., Grimm C.M., Gannon M.J., Chen, M-J. (1991): Organizational Information Processing: Competitive Responses and Performance in the U.S. Domestic Airline Industry. “Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 34, No. 1. Thorelli H. B. (1986): Networks: Between Markets and Hierarchies. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 7, No.1. Tomlinson P.R. (2010): Co-Operative Ties and Innovation: Some New Evidence for UK Manufacturing. “Research Policy”, Vol. 39, No. 6. Yami S., Castaldo S., Dagnino G.B., Le Roy F. (2010): Coopetition: Winning Strategies for the 21st Century. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham. Young G., Smith K.G, Grimm C.M. (1996): Austrian and Industrial Organization Perspectives on Firm-Level Competitive Activity and Performance. “Organization Science”, Vol. 7, No. 3. Zaheer A., Zaheer S. (1997): Catching the Wave: Alterness, Responsiveness, and Market Influence in Global Electronic. “Networks, Management Science”, Vol. 43, No. 11. 92 DOES COOPETITION STRATEGY IMPROVE MARKET PERFORMANCE?… Appendix Examples of categorization of competitive actions/reactions Types of actions 1 Competitive Action Date 2 Example 3 Pricing Action 08/05/02 E-Plus cuts prices to boost i-mode. German operator E-Plus has slashed the price of its i-mode handset. Marketing Action 05/03/02 EuroTel offers free usage: Czech operator EuroTel is offering customers three months of free data usage when they sign up for its GPRS service. Product Action 31/07/02 Wind launches mobile video. Italian cellco Wind announced that subscribers can now watch moving film pictures on their handsets, with content supplied via the LIBERO mobile portal. Capacity Action 28/02/01 Telekom Italian Mobile paid Real 1.54 billion for PCS operating licenses in Sao Paolo and the region of southern Brazil. The third license, covering the northern region, was awarded to telemar for US$ 556 million. Service Action 23/03/05 MobilTel launches EDGE: Leading Bulgarian operator MobilTel announced last week that it had launched EDGE services in Sofia and is working on a nationwide rollout. Signalling Action 02/02/05 Mobilkom makes 3G push: Austrian operator Mobilkom says it expects to offer nationwide 3G coverage by the summer using UMTS and EDGE Cingular Wireless and VoiceStream 05/07/00 Cingular finds Voice. Cingular Wireless (formerly BellSouth/SBC) and Voicestream last week exchanged spectrum that will allow Cingular to gain access to New York City, and VoiceStream to obtain additional spectrum in Los Angeles and San Francisco. Telstra (Australia) and PCCW (Hong Kong) 31/01/01 Telefonica Moviles (Spain) 17/04/02 Cooperative Actions Telstra, PCCW launch JVs. Australian operator Telstra and Hong Kong‘s PCCW have launched their Asia-Pacific alliance with three 50/50 joint venture companies. Telefonica signs roaming deals. Telefonica Moviles has signed a roaming agreement 93 F REDERIC L E ROY , F AMARA H YACINTHE S ANOU appendix cont. 1 NTT DoCoMo (Japan) SK Telecom (South Korea) 94 2 3 with SK Telecom and NTT DoCoMo, enabling Telefonica’s subscribers to send and receive voice, SMS and data services in time for this summer’s soccer World Cup Patrycja Klimas University of Economics in Katowice, Poland MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION INSIDE AN AVIATION SUPPLY CHAIN – THE CASE OF THE AVIATION VALLEY P ATRYCJA K LIMAS Abstract In recent years the concept of coopetition becomes more and more popular in both economy and literature. The growing interest in coopetition strategies, their characteristics and adaptation stems from the fact that it may be perceived as a significant factor for leveraging effectiveness and performance of modern organizations. Drawn from existing literature this paper attempts to present the character of coopetition inside the aviation supply chain. By identifying different levels, scopes and fields of both cooperation and competition four types of coopetition were identified. In the light of the obtained results particular members of considered supply chain may be characterized by: national coopetition, global coopetition, hybrid coopetition and multidimensional coopetition. The identified types of coopetition are varied in terms of: a) the market scope of coopetition, b) types organizations engaged (i.e. subsidiaries / parent organizations), c) stages of supply chain maintaining coopetitive relationships, and d) complexity and directedness of coopetition. Keywords: coopetition, cooperation, competition, networks, supply chain, aviation, case study. Introduction Even though supply chains are not new phenomena, nowadays they are attracting greater and greater attention of researchers from management sciences (Wilhelm, 2011). The growing interest in supply chains within the management field may be justified by the fact that today in business practice supply chains as well as supply chain management are at the heart of successful business strategy (Houé and Guimaraes, 2013). In a traditional, management-based view supply chain is understood as a set of cooperating – in deferent aspects of activity – production, trading and service companies together with their clients among which the flows of products, information and money are realized (Witkowski, 2010). However, in more recent literature supply chains are perceived as a network of cooperating organizations engaged – through a set of relationships – in joint processes and activities creating values like products and services provided to the final clients (Christopher, 1998). Modern supply chains take the form of 96 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… network of companies, including suppliers and their suppliers, if they exist, and clients and their clients, if they exist (Lambert, 2008). Moreover, supply chains are co-created by a network of resources, materials, information and services (Chen and Paulraj, 2004) provided by all the above-mentioned organizations. To conclude, the newest view on supply chains assume that it is “a set of three or more entities directly involved in the upstream and downstream flow of products, services, finances, and information from a source to the customer” (Mentzner et al., 2001, p. 4) together with the dense network of diversified relationships among them. The aim of this paper is to present and discuss the results of the research on coopetition conduced within a supply chain. The coopetition as well as coopetitive relationships are explored from the perspective of the behaviors and strategies adopted by particular members of supply chain rooted in a Polish aviation industry. First, this research provides the diagnosis of coopetition features recognized among particular members of considered supply chain. Second, the research identifies the types of coopetition existing within the considered network of cooperation. The findings suggest that the particular members of supply chain are diverse in terms of coopetition strategies adopted. This paper is divided into four parts. The first section outlines the theoretical underpinnings for the phenomena of coopetition and coopetitive relationships in supply chains. The second part raises the methodological issues including research design and research methods. The third section presents the research results reflecting the coopetition phenomena inside one, purposefully chosen innovation network i.e. Aviation Valley. The findings are presented with a distinction into national coopetition, global coopetition, hybrid coopetition and multidimensional coopetition. Finally, the fourth section summarizes the outcomes of the conducted study, outlines the possible directions for further research, and points out the most important limitations of the research. 1. Theoretical background In business practice, modern supply chains function as multifaceted and highly complex networks (Houé and Guimaraes, 2013). They consists of multitude of stakeholders (Houé and Guimaraes, 2013) and dense network of complicated, strong, long-term, and interdependent relationships among partners developed and fostered through strategic collaboration (Cheh and Paulraj, 2004). Such a high level of complexity and diversity of links and organizations involved 97 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS causes that modern supply chain more often can be labelled as a multi-stage, multi-member, or multi-product (Sepehri and Fayazbakhsh, 2011). From the strategic management point of view it should be emphasized that supply chains are formed to achieve a greater level of sustainable competitive advantage for all parties involved (Cheng et al., 2008; Sepehri and Fayazbakhsh, 2011) what is attainable by combining individual strengths and unique resources of particular organizations through collaborative and dense relationships. In the literature on supply chains and supply chain management, there is emphasized not only the existence but also the significance of beneficial collaborative relationships (Christopher, 2001; Houé and Guimaraes, 2013) among particular partners. However, besides these purely collaborative links, members of supply chains are connected by – more or less – competitive relations, or coopetitive ties. In other words, among supply chain members we are able to identify three different conditions, namely: cooperation, competition and coopetition. It is worth noting that while the prior literature expressed rather the first situation only the latest research points out that today “members of a supply chain more often compete fiercely” (Sepehri and Fayazbakhsh, 2011, p. 61). It shows indirectly, that between partners maintaining collaborative relations more often appear coopetition and coopetitive relationships (Wilhelm, 2011). Indeed, in supply chain firms more willingly and more often simultaneously compete and co-operate in order to maximize their profits (Gurnani et al., 2007) and competitive advantage reached. Therefore coopetition can be perceived as a one of the distinctive feature of modern supply chains (Li et al., 2011) while their members are characterized by an inherent tension of cooperation and competition (Wilhelm, 2011). Furthermore, from the managerial perspective coopetition can be perceived as a factor of competitive advantage created by the whole supply chain as well as by its particular members (Li et al., 2011). This leveraging effect of coopetition for supply chain performance results from the development of many different cross-functional aspects of cooperation strengthening the cooperative intensity and influencing especially customer performance and financial performance (Luo et al., 2006). Moreover, the prior research on supply chains pointed out that coopetition among supply chain members provides greater results than their only competitive or collaborative approach (Sepehri and Fayazbakhsh, 2011). In other words the more coopetitive than only collaborative relationships within the supply chain the greater value and supply chain performance is reached. Most of prior research on relationships conducted under the conditions of supply chains has been focused on collaborative ties and cooperative connections. Unfortunately, only very few studies were conducted on the coexistence of 98 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… the cooperation and competition relationships between supply chain members (e.g. Chen, Paulraj, 2004). To the authors’ knowledge the coopetitive relationships perceived in theoretical papers as so significant (Li et al., 2011; Sepehri and Fayazbakhsh, 2011; Wilhelm, 2011) remain poorly and fragmentally recognized (Cheng et al., 2008) contributing to the fact that our knowledge about coopetitive relationships seems to be ambiguous, or even a little bit blurry. Firstly, previous research on coopetition among members of supply chains has investigated coopetition at the dyad level (i.e. coopetition has been considered between two organizations only – Gurnani et al., 2005) while the literature stresses that in case of coopetition inside supply chain we need a much wider, holistic approach considering coopetitive relationship inside the whole network of ties and connections among – and not only between – members of supply chain (Wilhelm, 2011). Secondly, prior research related to the phenomena of coopetition inside supply chain was devoted to comparisons of the collaborative, competitive and coopetitive behaviors of the supply chain members (Sepehri and Fayazbakhsh, 2011). Thirdly, the majority of prior research was explorative in nature (Gurnani et al., 2005; Lejeune and Yakova, 2005; Wilhelm, 2011; Sepehri and Fayazbakhsh, 2011) and only a slight research efforts were directed on explanation of the significance of coopetition for knowledge management and knowledgeintensive processes inside supply chains (e.g. Cheng et al., 2008; Li et al., 2011). To conclude, prior literature does not provide research on the specifics and nature of the coopetitive relationship in the strict sense, do not provide holistic perspective undertaken from the whole supply chain point of view. Generally the coopetition and coopetitive relationships still remain poorly recognized under the conditions of supply chains (Cheng et al., 2008). Therefore, further and deeper, theoretical and empirical, exploratory and explanatory research in exploring coopetition and coopetitive relationships is needed (Gurnani et al., 2005; Cheng et al., 2008; Wilhelm, 2011). Lack of comprehensive and holistic research on coopetition and coopetitive relationships among members of supply chains as well as the limitations of prior research outlined above seem to justify the existence of the research gap. This gap ought to be filled in by exploratory and qualitative research (Houé and Guimaraes, 2013). Therefore the goal of this paper is to present and discuss the results of the research on coopetition relationships within one, purposefully chosen supply chain. The results are presented and discussed though investigation of most important characteristics, main types and different variants of the identified coopetitive relationships among members of the networked supply chain. 99 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS 2. Research design* The Aviation Valley case aims at identifying the coopetition features and types related to the particular members of supply chain. Research on coopetition strategy and coopetitive relationships was grounded in Polish aviation industry. The choice of this industry is justified by several reasons: highly developed inter-organizational cooperation (caused by strong pressure to constantly be innovative and tremendous level of expenditure on R&D), high level of networking, above-average level of complexity and modularity of products manufactured by Polish aviation companies, specificity favouring establishment of supply chains (aviation industry consists mainly of SME subcontractors and suppliers, there are only several large, key companies manufacturing final products like aviation engines). In Poland, there are more than 120 companies working for aviation industry, employing over 25 thousand employees. Most of Polish aviation companies are members of Aviation Valley (AV) which was chosen for our investigation. The Aviation Valley is a registered association of companies and organizations active in the field of aeronautical manufacturing, research, training or exploitation. It has been founded very recently, yet has proven since 2003 to be a very effective horizontally integrated supply chain implementing cutting edge aviation technologies and providing state of the art aviation products including aeronautic engines, gliders, light planes, and helicopters. Between its creation date in 2003, where 17 founding members laid grounds for a formal industry association and now a sharp increase in membership can be noticed – it is now topping 95 firms and organizations. Since 2003, Aviation Valley functions as a cluster (as it is geographically concentrated), as an association (as it is registered as a NGO), as a supply chain (as it provide co-created and co-produced aviation engines, planes, gliders and other aviation products), as a chain in global value and supply chain (as it provides modular components for final producers like Boeing, Airbus, or Embraer). In 2013 there was more than 90 members, 23 500 employees and turnover exceeded 1 billion € – covering more than 80% of Polish aviation industry in terms of total employment and turnover. The size and obtained results locate Aviation * Research leading to the achievement of these results is conducted under FRIDA project (Fostering Regional Innovation and Development through Anchors and Networks) and has received support from the 7th European Commission Framework Programme (Socio-Economic and Humanities Sciences, contract number 225546). Furthermore, the preparation of this paper was supported also by a research grant from the National Science Centre under the project titled: Organisational Proximity in Innovation Networks (contract number: DEC-2011/03/N/HS4/00372). 100 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… Valley among the most important European aviation and aerospace clusters (Niosi and Zhegu, 2005). The Aviation Valley operates as a supply chain – especially – for three global aviation corporations: United Technology Corporation, Avio Group and Augusta Westland. The Aviation Valley is a cluster with three major geographical concentration areas: around the city of Rzeszów in southeastern Poland; around the city of Bielsko-Biała in southern Poland; around the city of Świdnik in eastern part of Poland, the distances between these subclusters exceeding 250 km in each direction. It should be added that every one of sub-clusters operate around one large company being the subsidiary of abovementioned global corporation. First, WSK Rzeszów owned by United Technology Corporation is the core for organizations operating around the city of Rzeszów. Second, Avio Polska owned by Avio Group is the core for organizations operating around the city of Bielsko-Biała. Third, PZL-Świdnik owned by Augusta Westland is the core for organizations operating around the city of Świdnik. The investigation of the coopetition and coopetitive relationships was restricted to a strategic alliance organized as a formal association as the literature states that coopetition can be identified and should be explored inside cooperative and formal supply chains (Sepehri and Fayazbakhsh, 2011). On the other hand, the restriction of research perspective to one, purposefully chosen supply chain can be justified by the qualitative, exploratory and explaining nature of the research aims, as well as by the existence of cognitive gaps and lack of previous research. Therefore, the research adopts a qualitative approach and applies an interpretative case study method (Stake, 2009) aiming at theory building (Andrade, 2009). Research design aims at identifying key features of coopetition characteristic for Aviation Valley members. Therefore a three step approach has been adopted. Firstly, secondary data (including articles, annual industry reports, purchasing information, and websites) was collected in order to briefly describe cluster relevant members, and identify their business profiles. Secondly, in order to identify coopetitors the analysis of the area of competition and cooperation within the supply chain has been conducted. In general, among the supply chain members 27 coopetitors were identified. Thirdly, primary data was collected to distinguish the most important features of coopetitive relationships maintained by identified coopetitors. In that part of the study 22 direct, semi-structured interviews were conducted. The owners, directors, vicepresidents and top managers played the role of our interlocutors. As an additional source of information the researchers run two observations during annual meetings of Aviation Valley members. It should be added that both, the primary and secondary data for the purposes of the research was collected between September 2010 and December 2011. 101 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS 3. Coopetition within a supply chain – the case of Aviation Valley Aviation Valley is the biggest, the oldest, the most developed formally registered supply chain in Polish aviation industry. Taking the perspective of its objectives and main characteristics it is an innovation network consisting of intensive, strong, and close cooperative and coopetitive relationships. Aviation industry – which creates the context for the activity of Aviation Valley – is knowledge intensive sector (Niosi and Zhegu, 2005), where innovations provide competitive advantage, and the processes of knowledge creation, knowledge acquiring, and knowledge sharing seems to be the overriding objectives (Broekel and Boschma, 2009; Dos Santos and Neto, 2009). Very often, the processes of searching new knowledge require external collaboration with customers, suppliers, science representatives and even with competitors (Niosi and Zhegu, 2005). Therefore the majority of collaborative initiatives, inter-organisational networks as well as formal and informal supply chains within aviation industry function as innovation networks inside which competition is accompanied by collaboration. Cooperation with competitors creates possibilities to improve quality, invent innovations (Hagberg-Andersson and Tidström, 2010), foster innovation and knowledge sharing (Osarenkhoe, 2010), and stimulate efficient knowledge management (Dos Santos and Neto, 2009). Furthermore, coopetition provides access to complementary resources (Luo and Slotegraaf, 2006) and to competitors’ skills and capabilities (Gnyawali and Park, 2009) which would be otherwise unavailable. All of the above-mentioned benefits of simultaneous cooperation and competition are important for Aviation Valley and its members what is reflected in its statute indicating one of the basic rule and goal of the association – “to combine healthy competition with cooperation in particular areas” (AV’s statute). The literature states that the significance of coopetition increases as products become more complex and as competition becomes global (Gnyawali and Park, 2009), and then it provides higher value in a shorter time than competitive orientation (Dagnino and Padula, 2002). Due to that coopetition seems to play an important role inside Aviation Valley being supply chain providing extremely complex and modular final products like aviation engines, planes, gliders and helicopters. The character of provided products and the existence of common goals of particular partners do not result in the fact that members are connected only by cooperative relationships. There are still some fields of activity reserved for competition, and the relationships between partners are rather coopetitive than 102 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… cooperative only. It is interesting as the supply chain members pay great attention to the isolation mechanism, and opportunistic behaviors which may appear during cooperation. That is why they delimit and respect the line between competition and cooperation – “We have non-aggression pact with companies from the Valley, we are aware in which areas there are opportunities for fruitful cooperation and which fields of our activity should be protected against – even the closest – our partners” (interviewee M); “We know where and how cooperate, and where do not incommode or disturb each other” (interviewee R). In the light of the above Aviation Valley can be described as a network being a dynamic combination of collaborative and competitive relationships and the loci of coopetition phenomena (Gnyawali and Park, 2009). In technology intensive and global competitive markets like aviation and aerospace adaptation of the coopetition strategy is often only one, possible way of survival and development. In case of considered supply chain SMEs’ perceive coopetition as a simple path to the innovativeness, technological improvements (Gnyawali and Park, 2009) and leveraging capacity – “If we cannot realize the order placed by foreign customer, we try to recommend some companies from the Valley, even our direct competitors” (interviewee N, medium organization); “Norbert Polska (one of the members of AV) has very similar machine park to us, it is our the biggest competitor, but we sometimes buy their products and services […] when we cooperate we do not show them some of our products […] we are afraid that they may steal them” (interviewee O, medium organization). Otherwise, from the largest members’ standpoint tight cooperation with competitors beyond joint R&D activities gives the possibility of building a welldeveloped and efficient supply chain. Integration of widely dispersed subcontractors and suppliers provides shorter lead-time, higher level of suppliers’ specialization and transport costs reduction (Niosi and Zhegu, 2005). All those coopetition benefits can be used for leveraging global competitiveness. Therefore the key network members introduce coopetition strategy to ensure efficient managing supply chain (Bakshi and Kleindorfer, 2009). The highly globalized nature of aviation industry causes that aerospace networks have not only strong internal, domestic connections but also are rooted in a dense mosaic of international and global links (Dos Santos and Neto, 2009). In case of AV its members carry out especially direct, cooperative and competitive activity on the domestic market, maintaining interdependent relationships with national partners. However, the majority of the biggest players being subsidiaries of global corporations (approximately 25% of AV – Table 1) maintain dense network of well developed relationships on the global market at the same time. 103 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS Table 1. AVA’s members owned by global corporations Polish subsidiary Avio Polska CAV Aerospace Goodrich Krosno Kennametal Polska M&M Aerospace PZL Mielec PZL-Świdnik Hispano Suiza Polska WSK Rzeszów Zakład Kużnia Matrycowa Siemens Polska Vac Aero Kalisz Kreisler Polska King & Fowler Polska MTU Aero Engines Polska BorgWarner Turbo Systems Poland Sandvik Polska Hamilton Sundstrand Poland Parent company Avio Group CAV Aerospace Limited Goodrich Corporation Kennametal B/E Aerospace Sikorsky Aircraft Corporation* Augusta Westland Safran Group Pratt and Whitney* Ladish Group Siemens Vac Aero Kreisler Manufacturing Corporation King & Fowler MTU Aero Engines BorgWarner Turbo Systems Sandvik Group Hamilton Sundstrand* Headquarters Italy UK USA USA USA USA UK/Italy France USA USA Germany Canada USA UK Germany USA Sweden USA * Owned by United Technology Corporation (UTC), USA. Those companies cooperate within cluster on industry development on both the national and global level. They build efficient supply chain consisting of SMEs by supporting shared production processes, stimulating procurement processes, facilitating warehousing, and conducting joint research. Simultaneously, they compete with other large and medium organizations in different fields of activity, namely production processes, innovation processes, sales and distribution. Furthermore, it is possible that at the same time their parent companies compete strongly at the global market of final products (e.g. engines, helicopters) or cooperate in the field of global R&D while the subsidiaries are connected through competitive, cooperative or coopetitive relationships on the domestic market. Therefore, there are processes of simultaneous cooperation and competition at the national level (subsidiaries operating within a Polish cluster) and coopetition taking place around the globe (parent companies operating at the global market – Dos Santos and Neto, 2009). The complexity and parallelism of coopetition trajectories (Bonel and Rocco, 2007) requires taking different levels of coopetition into consideration (Fig. 1). Such bi-level (national-global), holistic view indicates the multidimensional nature of coopetition. 104 MULTIFACE ETED NATUR RE OF COOPE ETITION… Figure 1. Typology of coopetitioon in depend dence of levvel of cooperration and competition First, natiional coopetiition – the simultaneity s of cooperatiion and com mpetition at the nationnal level. Thee first aspectt of national coopetition is i related to the national cooperaation which – to the authoors’ knowled dge – is two-ffaceted. Firstlly, it refers to the relaationships bettween produccers and subccontractors (777% of AVA A members are small and a medium suppliers andd subcontracttors – Fig. 2) which coopeerate tightly as the final products are a highly coomplex, extreemely moduular and technnologically advanced – „It is impoortant to deveelop and expaand network of subcontracctors along the supplyy chain, they should by loccated close to o each other, in one particcular region and be sim milar in termss of competennces” (intervieewee W). 105 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS Figure 2. Supply chaain in aviatioon industry On the t other hannd cluster’s members co ollaborate inn research projects. In general, the t creation of aviation innovations, i new technoologies and kknowledge takes placce mainly through coopeeration and coopetition c u under researcch projects supportedd by Polish government and Europeean funds. Fast F changingg environment andd shortening product liffe cycles caall for collabboration (Am mankwahAmoah annd Debrah, 2011) 2 even with w direct co ompetitors. Indeed, I moree often the best partnner is the grreatest comppetitor (Chien n and Peng,, 2005) becaause it has appropriate and suitabble knowledge potential as well as technological t l advancement – thhe need of brridging the resource initiatives. r gap p stimulates cooperative c Moreoverr rapid and raadical technoological chan nges cause inncrease of R R&D costs. Therefore more and more m market members m wass looking for financial suppport being are more willing for collaboration c n on joint reesearch projeects (Niosi aand Zhegu, petitive advanntage (Bonell and Roc2005) enaabling to achhieve collectiively a comp co, 2007)). Joint impllementation of research projects alllows the suppply chain members to shorten thhe time of development d of new techhnologies andd to divide ng the most significant bbenefits of significannt expenditurre on innovaations. Amon joint impllementation of research projects listed by aviation organizattions there are: natioonal and inteernational buusiness contaacts, access to t expertise and trainings, intanngible resourrces of businness partnerss, exchange of o knowledgee, technology and experience. e T above-m The mentioned imp plications off collaborativve processes are nooticed mainlyy by SMEs while the biggest b and the t strongesst cluster’s members play the rolles of innovaation brokerrs. They suppport SMEs bby helping them idenntifying theirr innovation and a knowled dge needs, seetting up andd managing the inter-organisationnal cooperation processes (Batterink et al., 20100). Indeed, n archhitects, operaators and carretakers (Snoow et al., 19992) being they are network responsible for netwoork managem ment (Möllerr et al., 20055) and leverraging network perfformance. On O the other hand the big ggest organiisations are aaware that 106 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… only very cohesive supply chain can be the real vehicles of knowledge spillovers (Niosi and Zhegu, 2005) and innovation flows accelerators. It is also worth to add that to the great extent the development and the cohesion of the cooperation under the supply chain are mainly due to these large organizations and their overlapping objectives. Basically their highly complex and modular activity require a well operating vertical supply chain of diversified suppliers and subcontractors as long as they have to face extremely high coopetition at the global market – “[…] We have to form and support well-functioning, vertical supply chain […] to be able to provide final products” (interviewee W). To sum up, the whole supply chain is developed though research projects, among the most important AV’s projects there are AERONET, CEKSO, Technological Foresight, Joint Sky, Research and Development Laboratory for Aviation Materials (Table 2). Table 2. Collaboration through research projects AERONET CEKSO INTERREG IIIA Technological foresight Joint Sky Enterprise Europe Network Wings for Regions Aeropolis Projects Centre of Advanced Technologies; development of aviation technologies and materials Regional Centre for Transfer of Modern Technology; education of future workforce in Practical Training Centers for CNC operators Development and promotion of cross-border Polish-Ukrainian aviation cluster Directions of development of material technologies Development and integration of the innovating aviation cluster; development of communication and knowledge exchange Knowledge and state of the art technology transfer Development of cooperation between leading European aviation clusters Technology Park In general, collaboration is strong side of Aviation Valley. It is not surprising since joint effort of different players in the value chain provide technological improvements and innovations (Cassiman, 2009). However, it should be noticed that the collaborative processes refers – only – to the one side of national coopetition within considered supply chain. Simultaneously, coopetition at the national level covers the competitive processes connecting particular members of the supply chain. Aviation Valley concentrates almost the entire Polish aviation industry. Therefore it should not be surprising that within cluster there are some direct and indirect competitors. Generally the considered supply chain consists of independent, loosely coupled organizations differentiated in terms of size and ownership. They can also be divided according to the level of value chain at which they operate and according to the level of competition inside the network (Table 3). 107 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS Table 3. Example of competitors in the domestic market Supply chain raw materials hardware different types of machining special processes original elements Example members Alinox Arkom HSW Narzędziownia Marco Expot-Import TW Metals BE Aerospace Technology Management Consultants-Poland Admil Aviomechanika Creuzet Fin Iwamet Remog Ultratech Cerel EL Automatyka King and Fowler Vac Aero Avio Polska Goodrich Krosno Hispano Suiza MTU Aero Engines Pratt and Whitney Kalisz PZL Mielec PZL Świdnik WSK Rzeszów Size Competition level local & national local & national small and medium local & national local & national large national & global indirectly Particular levels of value chain represent different areas of competition. The competitive relationships are differentiated. Most of AV’s members are subcontractors and suppliers. Here the most intensive competition is reflected in the field of raw materials and treatment processes. Moreover most of subcontractors are Polish SMEs which compete on domestic market, within Polish part of global value chain. On the other hand AV’s members owned by global corporations compete at the market of original elements (e.g. blades, turbines, engines) at both domestic and global level. The essence of coopetition is that companies compete and cooperate parallelly in different fields of activity. The national coopetition arises from overlapping national cooperation and national competition (Table 4) and can be described as coopetition strategy on meso level (Dagnino and Padula, 2002). 108 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… Table 4. Review of coopetition areas at national level Cooperation Margański & Mysłowski Rzeszów University of Technology Competition testing of composites new composite technologies Margański & Mysłowski PZL Świdnik Avio Polska WSK Rzeszów MTU Aero Engines Rzeszów University of Technology Avio Polska Rzeszów University of Technology research on aircraft turbines energy-saving turbines WSK Rzeszów Rzeszów University of Technology research on aerospace propulsion drive boxes Rzeszów University of Technology Warsaw University of Technology* multifunction moto-glider light and ultra-light gliders Royal Star Fly WSK Rzeszów PZL Mielec testing new products and service pilot trainings Aviomechanika Norbert Polska thermal and electro-chemical treatment machining Avio Polska WSK Rzeszów Margański & Mysłowski Rzeszów University of Technology Warsaw University of Technology* PZL Mielec Rzeszów University of Technology Royal Star Fly Aviomechanika Norbert Polska Arkom Erkom * Does not belong to the AV. Considering coopetition strategy among the set of independent organizations the broaden view is needed. Particular member can compete in one area with one network member (A) and at the same time it may cooperate within that area with another (B). On the other hand that particular member can cooperate with some network members (A or/and B) in one area and at the same time compete with them within different fields of activity. Thus within the Aviation Valley the complex network coopetition (Dagnino and Padula, 2002) can be identified. The existing literature states that coopetition is a combination (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000; Gnyawali and Park, 2009; Li et al., 2011) of appropriate level of competition and cooperation. Base on the intensity of those relationships Luo distinguishes four types of approach to coopetition (Osarenkhoe, 2010): alienator (monoplayer), contender, partner and co-opetitor (adapter). These types differ also in rent-seeking strategic behaviours (Lado, 1997). Within the Aviation Valley all of these coopetition models are introduced (Fig. 3.) as the network members apply differentiated configurations of competitive and cooperative relationships. 109 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS Figure 3. Example of different types of coopetition among AVA. High Cooperative orientation Low Competitive orientation Low High Partner displaying collaborative Co-opetitor (Adapter) rent-seeking behavior, displaying syncretic e.g. Rzeszów University rent-seeking behavior, of Technology e.g. WSK Rzeszów Alienator (Monoplayer) displayContender displaying ing monopolistic rent-seeking competitive rent-seeking behavior, behavior, e.g. Cerel e.g. PZL Świdnik Source: Based on Luo’s typology [Luo et al., 2006] First, monoplayer (or alienator) maintains low degree of both cooperation and competition. For instance Cerel Energy Institute does not show strong engagement in cluster’s activity. It remains on the periphery of the cluster – “It is good to have Valley’s logo on our website, it adds prestige, but nothing more” said Cerel’s director. Second, contender maintains high degree of competition and low degree of cooperation. Within Aviation Valley PZL Świdnik introduces a contender model. It competes e.g. with WSK Rzeszów at the nacelles market and with Norbert Polska at the engine cowling market. On the other hand it does not show strong commitment in cooperation within the cluster – „We are a little bit on the edge of the Valley […] we do not have the material advantages, in case of projects we prefer cooperate internationally” (R&D manager, PZL Świdnik). Third is partner that exhibits strong willingness to cooperate and aversion to compete and in case of AV the Rzeszów University of Technology (RUT) displays this approach. It participates in most of the projects conducted within AV, very often even as a coordinator or initiator – „We need urgently good regional aviation, which is why we have to cooperate” (RUT professor). On the other hand it is public university, so it does not engage in economic activity in the aviation sector. Therefore RUT does not display competitive behaviors. Last, but not lest is the co-opetitor which maintains high degree of cooperation and competition. In case of Aviation Valley the WSK Rzeszów could be an example of the adaptation of this type of coopetition strategy. It is strongly engaged in the most of cooperative projects and initiatives and at the same time it doggedly competes with Avio Polska (turbines, blades) or PZL Świdnik (engines) at the national level. As you can notice all of the considered above coopetition models are differentiated in terms of coopetitive relationships (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000). A cooperation-dominated relationship appears when coopetitive relationships consist of more cooperation than competition 110 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… (typical for partner’s approach). A competition-dominated relationship occurs when coopetitive relationship includes more competition than cooperation (standard for contenders). Finally, an equal relationship appears when cooperation and competition are equally distributed (characteristic for alienators and co-opetitors). Second, global coopetition – the simultaneity of cooperation and competition at the international level. While Polish branches and subsidiaries coopete, cooperate or compete among Aviation Valley’s boundaries restricted to the borders of Poland (national level), their global owners cooperate, compete, coopete internationally (global level) –Figure 1. The global corporations represented in AV belong to the world's leading aerospace and aviation companies. They are main suppliers and subcontractors for such companies like Boeing, Airbus, Bombardier, Embrayer, or Lockheed Martin. At the global level they also have to deal with global competitors like Turbomeca, Snecma, Rolls-Royce, Renault, GE Aviation, Tusas Engine Industries, or Volvo Aero. The nature of the global aerospace industry motivate to (or even impose) international collaboration, but at the same time high global competition cannot be removed. Therefore global aviation companies just as their subsidiaries at national level, implement coopetition strategies at the global one. It means that they maintain both, competitive and cooperative relationships with members of global aviation industry (Table 5). For example MTU Aero Engines and Avio Group cooperate with global leaders on new, high-efficient liquid fuel while United Technology Corporation conducts research in the same area on its own. At the same time UTC together with Avio Group is working on new low-pressure turbine and together with MTU Aero Engines on blades improvements. Table 5. Review of cooperative and competitive fields of activity between aviation world leaders Global corporations 1 2 United Technology Corporation (Hamilton Augusta Sundstrand Power SysWestland tems; Sikorsky) United Technology Corporation (Pratt and WhitSafran ney Canada) United Technology Corporation (Pratt and WhitAvio Group ney Canada) United Technology CorMTU Aero poration (Pratt and WhitEngines ney Canada, Sikorsky) Cooperation 3 Competition 4 Electric power, engine control systems, gearboxes Helicopters Shafts for aircraft engines Engine components – gears, housings Low pressure turbines and the power transmission Turbofan power plant systems, blades and turbines Engine components – blades and turbines Liquid fuels 111 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS table 5 cont. 1 2 MTU Aero Engines Avio Group Avio Group Augusta Westland 3 Atomization and combustion of liquid fuels Joint Technology Initiative (JTI) – clean sky 4 Engine components – blades and turbine components In the helicopter sector, Avio cooperate with GE Aviation and UTC – main competitors of Augusta Westland Considering the nature of global coopetition, the configuration of cooperative and competitive relationships fully reflects the characteristic of national coopetition (cf. Tables 4 and 5). Global corporations are more willing to cooperate in the first stages of global value chain and are more focused on competition in the final ones (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000). However, there is significant difference between national and global coopetition. In case of global coopetition strategy there are no restrictions on the selection of partner for collaboration. For example Avio Group and MTU Aero Engines cooperate with the main competitors of UTC which remain outside the main and basic supply chain providing e.g. aviation engines. But at the national level, within Aviation Valley it is forbidden to maintain collaborative relationships with the most dangerous competitors not belonging to the cluster and remaining outside the supply chain – “Cooperation with GE or Rolls-Royce is frowned upon. You know they are the great trinity: GE, UTC and Rolls-Royce. If you provide something for UTC you can forget about the other two and vice versa. We are in Rolls-Royce and GE’s databases but it is better to not cooperate with them” (vice president of medium enterprise). The difference between national and global coopetition inside aviation industry results from the nature of relationships between companies. Global corporations are completely autonomous. In turn, AV’s members form a cohesive cluster together and they have to adhere to the generally applicable principles of cooperation imposed by the whole strategic network. They have to comply even if they remain formally and officially independent. For instance, Zakład Kuźnia Matrycowa supplies rugged, reliable, high-quality forgings for the most important AV’s players (e.g. Avio Polska, Goodrich Krosno, Hamilton Sunstrand Polska, WSK Rzeszów, MTU Aero Engines Polska and PZL Mielec) and it does not provide (and according to the statute of AV it is not allowed to provide) any services for aviation companies remaining outside the cluster. At the same time its parent company (Ladish Corp.) is a subcontractor for GE Avia- 112 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… tion, Rolls-Royce, Tusas Engine Industries and Volvo Aero – the greatest competitors of UTC, MTU Aero Engines and Avio. Third, hybrid coopetition – the simultaneity of national (global) cooperation and global (national) competition at the international level. Hybrid coopetition occurs when: a) subsidiaries at national level cooperate with each other, while their parent companies compete at global level, or b) subsidiaries compete at national level, while their parent companies cooperate with each other at global level one. One of the common forms of hybrid coopetition in aviation industry is coopetition in the sphere of R&D. At the national level AV’s members cooperate though participation in wide range of research projects that aims at gaining financial support, inventing new components or developments of provided engines. At the same time their parent companies compete globally at the sphere of R&D activity trying to win the race for new technologies and improvements of the final products like aircraft and aerospace engines. For instance, MTU Aero Engines and Avio Group cooperate separately with Turbomeca, Snecma, Rolls-Royce and Renault together on new, high-efficient liquid fuel. In other words, at the global market they realize separate, competitive research projects which aims are covering. At the same time, the MTU Aero Engines and Avio's subsidiaries cooperate at the Polish market for instance within AERONET on composite technologies. Fourth, multidimensional coopetition – the simultaneity of national coopetition and global coopetition. The most complex dimension of coopetition refers to the situation when companies adopt coopetition strategies at both global and national level. Within Aviation Valley the multidimensional coopetition occurs when both subsidiary and its parent company adopt coopetition strategy. Therefore multidimensional coopetition affects only the largest and the most important members with international roots. From the perspective of particular members of Polish supply chain multidimensional coopetition refer to the situation when they coopete directly at national level and simultaneously coopete indirectly (through their parents companies) at the global one. For instance Avio Polska (owned by Avio Group) is connected with PZL Świdnik (owned by Augusta Westland) by coopetitive relationships as they cooperate in the area of production of the composites and compete in the field of energy-saving turbines. At the same time Avio Group (owner of Avio Polska) is connected with Augusta Westland (owner of PZL Świdnik) by coopetitive relationships as they cooperate under the Joint Technology Initiative of and compete on the market of helicopters. In such situation Polish subsidiaries coopete directly at the national level and coopete indirectly at the global level what is characteristic for multidimensional coopetion. 113 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS Conclusions Coopetition can be identified when cooperative and competitive relationships are identified at the same time, and competition and cooperation between independent organizations are implemented in parallel. In case of considered network, being complex supply chain and an integral part of global aviation/aerospace value chain, coopetition seems to be multifaceted phenomena. It can be identified between varied stages of supply chain and observed at different levels of aviation activity. In authors’ opinion it is possible to distinguish four types of coopetition inside supply chain, namely: national coopetition, global coopetition, hybrid coopetition and multidimensional ones. All of the abovementioned types of coopetition are varied in terms of: a) the market scope of coopetition, b) types organizations engaged (i.e. subsidiaries/parent organizations), c) stages of supply chain maintaining coopetitive relationships, and d) complexity and directedness of coopetition. First, the simplest variant of coopetition is the national coopetition referring to simultaneous cooperation and competition at the national level and reflecting joint occurrence of cooperation and competition across functional areas within cooperating members of supply chain (Luo et al., 2006). Inside Aviation Valley national coopetition takes place at the early stages of the overall global value chain (Figure 2). This level of coopetition applies to all cluster members implementing coopetitive strategy: all members of supply chain coopete in the field of R&D, but the SMEs coopete also in the area of aviation components and special processes provided for the largest organizations (subsidiaries of global corporations). Second, the geographically distant global coopetition referring to simultaneous cooperation and competition at the global level. In case of Aviation Valley global coopetition takes place at the final stages of the overall global value chain (Figure 2) and is related to large organizations being subsidiaries of global corporations. These supply chain members owned by international corporations are indirectly related to each other by cooperative and competitive relationships at the global level as they parent companies maintain cooperative and competitive relationships with each other at the global market, at the stage of final products. In other words, in global coopetition it is possible to identify indirect coopetitive relationships between subsidiaries as they owners adopt coopetition strategy at the global level. Third, hybrid coopetition referring to simultaneous cooperation and competition at the global and national level at the same time (a combination of national competition/cooperation and global cooperation/competition). Inside Aviation Valley hybrid coopetition takes place at the all of the stages of the overall 114 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… global value chain (Fig. 2). For instance, a parent company competes for final product market at the global level (cooperates on research and development of new products at the global level) while its subsidiary cooperates on joint implementation of the research project at national level (competes on sales of aviation components at national level). It should be added that that type of coopetition occurs rather temporarily and is related mainly to the largest and the most important members of AV having global owners. Last, but not least dimension of coopetition within supply chain is a multidimensional coopetition referring to simultaneous cooperation and competition at the global and national level at the same time. As opposed to the hybrid coopetition it appears when both subsidiary and its parent company implement coopetition strategies and coopetition takes place simultaneously on two levels: global and national. It means that both the subsidiary and parent organization maintain coopetitive relationships. It is the most advanced and complex coopetitive interdependences related especially to the most important players within national supply chain and global value chain. In case of Aviation Valley multidimensional coopetition takes place across all of the stages of the overall global value chain (Fig. 2). To summarize, the plurality of coopetition levels and dimensions makes Aviation Valley intensive coopetition network (Chi et al., 2008) organized as a formal cluster consisting of independent however interdependent supply chain members. It is copious in both competitive and cooperative relationships. There are many competitors connected by coopetitive relationships at several levels of supply chain (Table 4 and 5). Within the domestic part of the global supply chain the cooperative relationships appear mainly at the early stages, especially in the R&D activity whilst the competitive ones occur especially at the final stages, in the field of finished aircrafts and its finished components. The obtained results remain in line with prior research on coopetition pointing out that the closer to the customer or final product, the stronger the competition between business network partners (Bengtsson and Kock, 2000). It should be highlighted that network members are varied by the complexity and dimensionality of introduced coopetition strategy. The less complex and more one-dimensional coopetition refers rather to SMEs than to large organizations. On the other hand the most advanced and sophisticated variants of coopetition, i.e. multidimensional and hybrid coopetition are related to the most significant companies with strong international connections and global roots. The differences in the intensity and specificity of coopetition among and between particular members of supply chain are important as the nature of compe- 115 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS tition between coopetitors affects the level of cooperation they provide to each other (Gurnani et al., 2007). Therefore it can be said that these differences are reflected in the intensity and complexity of relationships, in the possible and achievable benefits of cooperation, and in the level of competitive advantage reached due to more or less intensive coopetition (Gurnani et al., 2007). Moreover there are both intentional and emerging coopetition (Czakon, 2009). Intentional coopetition refers rather to the largest and the most important network actors, while emerging coopetition refers to the SMEs. It points out the differences in the approach to the coopetition strategy adopted. The largest organizations seem to adopt intentional, purposefully benefit-oriented coopetition strategies while the SME supply chain members rather prefer the emerging approach appreciating and utilizing the benefits of coopetition strategy during its implementation. In conclusion it should be said that the authors are aware of some limitations related to the presented considerations. The majority of them results from the methodological approach adopted. The research was based on a single, interpretative case study (Stake, 2009) aimed at theory building what we see as a barrier to generalization. Furthermore, all of the above-mentioned considerations refer to the coopetition phenomena observed in one, purposefully chosen supply chain functioning under specific, high-tech, networked and globalised environment. It means that the process of drawing general conclusions and statements ought to be careful, prudent and rather limited. However, the nature of the study was rather exploratory than explanatory what justifies the conclusions drawn based on one intentionally chosen case. To the authors’ knowledge and besides all of the above-mentioned limitations the conducted research sheds some new light on the coopetition concept – especially in the field of the characteristic and specificity of coopetitive ties between and among cooperating competitors. The studies have proved the complexity and multidimensionality of coopetitive relations and have pointed out that the particular connections between coopetitors can be not only cooperative and competitive at the same time, but also that they can be varied in terms of level and scope of coopetition including national, global and multidimensional coopetition. Moreover the research has revealed some differences between large and SMEs in terms of the level of coopetition adopted. In authors’ opinion that last aspect should be explored deeper in future research as the differences between large companies and SMEs in their strategic approaches, performances and scope of activity may be connected with the level of the maintained coopetitive relationships within supply chain. 116 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… Acknowledgements The preparation of this paper was supported by a research grant from the National Science Centre under the project titled: Organisational Proximity in Innovation Networks (contract number: DEC-2011/03/N/HS4/00372). I would like also to acknowledge the help of all individuals who made important contributions to improving this paper including: professor Czakon, who offered his comments about the structure of the paper, and two anonymous reviewers of the last version of the paper submitted to the “Journal of Economics and Management”. References Amankwah-Amoah J., Debrah Y.A. (2011): The Evolution of Alliances in the Global Airline Industry: A Review of the African Experience. “Thunderbird International Business Review”, No. 53(1). Andrade A.D. (2009): Interpretive Research Aiming at Theory Building: Adopting and Adapting the Case Study Design. “The Qualitative Report”, No. 14(1). Bakshi N., Kleindorfer P. (2009): Co-Opetition and Investment for Supply-Chain Resilience. “Production and Operations Management”, No. 18(6). Batterink M.H., Wubben E.F.M., Klerkx L., Omtaa S.W.F. (2010): Orchestrating Innovation Networks: The Case of Innovation Brokers in the Agri-Food Sector. “Entrepreneurship & Regional Development”, No. 22. Bengtsson M., Kock S. (2000): Coopetition in Business Networks – to Cooperate and Compete Simultaneously. “Industrial Marketing Management”, No. 29. Bonel E., Rocco E. (2007): Coopeting to Survive; Surviving Coopetition. “International Studies of Management & Organization”, No. 37(2). Broekel T., Boschma R. (2009): Knowledge Networks in the Dutch Aviation Industry: The Proximity Paradox. “Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography”, No. 09.15. Cassiman B., Di Guardo M.C., Valentini G. (2009): Organising R&D Projects to Profit From Innovation: Insights From Co-opetition. “Long Range Planning”, No. 42. Chen I.J., Paulraj A. (2004): Towards a Theory of Supply Chain Management: The Constructs and Measurements. “Journal of Operations Management”, No. 22. Cheng J.H., Yeh Ch.H., Tu Ch.W. (2008): Trust and Knowledge Sharing in Green Supply Chains. “Supply Chain Management: An International Journal”, No. 13(4). Chi L., Holsapple C.W, Srinivasan C. (2008): Digital Systems, Partnership Networks, and Competition: The Co-Evolution of IOS Use and Network Position as Antecedents of Competitive Action. “Journal of Organizational Computing and Electronic Commerce” Vol. 18 (1), pp. 61-94. 117 P ATRYCJA K LIMAS Chien, T-H., Peng, T-J. (2005): Competition and Cooperation Intensity in a Network – A Case Study in Taiwan Simulator Industry. ”Journal of American Academy of Business Cambridge”, No. 7(2). Christopher M. (1998): Logistics and Supply Chain Management: Strategies for Reducing Costs and Improving Service. Financial Times, Prentice Hall, London. Christopher M. (2001): Logistics and Supply Chain Management: Creating Value-Adding Networks. 4th edition, Prentice Hall, London. Czakon W. (2009): Power Asymmetries, Flexibility and the Propensity to Coopete: An Empirical Investigation of SMEs’ Relationships with Franchisors. ”International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business”, No. 8(1). Dagnino G.B., Padula G. (2002): Coopetition Strategy: A New Kind of Interfirm Dynamics for Value Creation. Proceedings of the EURAM Conference, May. Dos Santos I.C., Neto J.A. (2009): Knowledge Management in a High Technology Industry. “International Journal of Innovation and Technology Management”, No. 6(2). Gnyawali D.R., Park R. (2009): Co-opetition and Technological Innovation in Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises: A Multilevel Conceptual Model. “Journal of Small Business Management”, No. 47. Gurnani H., Erkoc M., Luo Y. (2007): Production, Manufacturing and Logistics. Impact of Product Pricing and Timing of Investment Decisions on Supply Chain Co-Opetition. “European Journal of Operational Research”, No. 180. Hagberg-Andersson A., Tidström A. (2010): Capabilities Needed in Managing Coopetitive Business Relationships. Proceedings of the EURAM Conference, May. Houé T., Guimaraes R. (2013): A Diversity of Supply Chain Management: Towards a Geo-Explicative Model Explaining Coordination. Proceedings of the EURAM Conference, May. Lado A.A., Boyd N.G., Hanlon S.C. (1997): Competition, Cooperation, and the Search for Economic Rents: A Syncretic Model. “Academy of Management Review”, No. 22(1). Lambert D.M. (2008): Supply Chain Management: Processes, Partnerships, Performance. 3rd edition, Supply Chain Management Institute, Sarasota. Lejeune M,A., Yakova N. (2005): On Characterizing the 4 C’s in Supply Chain Management. “Journal of Operations Management”, No. 23. Li Y., Liu Y., Liu H. (2011): Co-Opetition, Distributor’s Entrepreneurial Orientation and Manufacturer’s Knowledge Acquisition: Evidence from China. “Journal of Operations Management”, No. 29. Luo X., Slotegraaf R.J., Pan X. (2006): Cross-Functional “Coopetition”: The Simultaneous Role of Cooperation and Competition Within Firms. “Journal of Marketing”, No. 70. 118 MULTIFACETED NATURE OF COOPETITION… Mentzer, J.T., DeWitt, W., Keebler, J.S., Min, S., Nix, N.W., Smith, C.D., Zacharia, Z.G. (2001): Defining Supply Chain Management. “Journal of Business Logistics”, No. 22(2). Möller K., Rajala A., Svahn S. (2005): Strategic Business Nets – Their Type and Management. “Journal of Business Research”, No. 58. Niosi J. Zhegu M. (2005): Aerospace Clusters: Local or Global Knowledge Spillovers? “Industry and Innovation”, No. 12(1). Osarenkhoe A. (2010): A Study of Inter-Firm Dynamics Between Competition and Cooperation – A Coopetition Strategy. ”Database Marketing & Customer Strategy Management”, No. 17(3/4). Sepehri M., Fayazbakhsh K. (2011): A Quantitative Examination of Competition, Coopetition and Cooperation in Supply Chains. “South African Journal of Business Management”, Vol. 42(3). Snow Ch.C., Miles R.E., Coleman H.J. (1992): Managing 21st Century Network Organizations. “Organizational Dynamics”, No. 20. Stake R.E. (2009): Jakościowe studium przypadku. In: Eds. N.K. Denzin, Y.S. Lincoln: Metody badań jakościowych. WN PWN, Warszawa. Wilhelm M.M. (2011): Managing Coopetition Through Horizontal Supply Chain Relations: Linking Dyadic and Network Levels of Analysis. “Journal of Operations Management”, No. 29. Witkowski J. (2010): Zarządzanie łańcuchem dostaw. Koncepcje. Procedury. Doświadczenia. PWE, Warszawa. 119 Wojciech Czakon, Karolina Mucha‐Kuś Mariusz Rogalski University of Economics in Katowice, Poland COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE – A SYSTEMATIC LITERATURE REVIEW 1997-2010 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI Abstract This paper adopts the approach of systematic review and provides a synthesis of the literature on coopetition in management and strategy. Our review focuses first on the phenomenon features, and offers a consensus-based definition. Next, we address the theoretical frameworks used by researchers and examine the linkage with related fields in order to outline the distinctive lines of coopetition versus alliances. Then we review the empirical foci adopted in published work to identify both preferred and underexplored areas of extant academic attention. We draw a research agenda oriented at further exploration of coopetition morphology, elucidating the stability issue and examining coopetition along the antecedents-process-outcomes trail. Keywords: coopetition, management, strategy, literature review. Introduction Coopetition has enjoyed a sustained rise to recognition across management literature (Yami, Le Roy, Castaldo, Dagnino, 2010; Gnyawali, Park, 2011). The term refers to the simultaneous use of cooperation and competition in order to achieve better collective and individual results. Coopetition helps firms to improve performance (Le Roy, Marques, Robert, 2009), increase market share (Meade, Hyman, Blank, 2009) or to develop new technologies and products (Quintara-Garcia, Benavides-Velasco, 1996). Theoretical contributions suggest that coopetition is the best strategic option for firms (Brandenburger, Nalebuff, 1996), and takes account of both competitive and collaborative advantages (Lado, Boyle, Hanlon, 1997). There are several reasons for undertaking a literature review on coopetition. Firstly, the term has been coined by managers who acknowledge the need to use both cooperation and competition with the same set of firms. Hence, the relevance of coopetition is recognized since its inception. Secondly, the growing body of literature offers the opportunity to develop coopetition theory further than it has been done so far. Thirdly, the delimitation of coopetition versus related concepts remains unclear. Coopetition extensively draws on cooperative interorganizational relationships literature, making the concept’s boundaries blurry. Specifically, it remains unclear whether coopetition is a separate phenomenon, with distinctive conceptual and methodological grounds, or whether it 122 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… is a combinative concept. Combinations typically draw on concepts from root fields, which inevitably leads to paradigmatic tensions. Fourthly, coopetition phenomenon recognition remains relatively weak in mainstream management literature so that the concept is still promising instead of becoming accomplished. The aim of this research is to address the state of the art and emerging research topics within the coopetition literature. The paper is organized in four sections. We begin by outlining the systematic review method (Tranfield et al., 2003) and provide key bibliometrics on the reviewed literature. The second section highlights the concept’s origins and the features attributed to coopetition in the literature. On that base we propose a coopetition definition, as a literature based consensus. Then, we examine the theoretical lenses used by researchers to study coopetition. This helps to point out to differences against alliances and unveil under exploited approaches. Next, empirical studies extracted from citation databases are reviewed, and an up-to-date analysis of the emerging trend is tabulated. This reveals a number of gaps in terms of industries, levels of analysis, and key topics of scrutiny. Finally, a critical discussion on the emerging research agenda is developed. 1. Method A growing recognition of literature review rigour’s importance stems from recent published works (Lee, 2009). Systematic literature review provides an audit line for reviewing literature, as it uses databases selection and search in order to explicitly demonstrate how relevant literature has been extracted from the existing body of literature. Further, it uses bibliometrics to identify trends and structures within the publications under scrutiny. In this study we draw on frequency analysis in order to identify coopetition features and citation analysis. Then, we exploit critical literature review techniques in order to draw conclusions on coopetition research, identify gaps in current understanding and recommend further research agenda. Most of the existing contributions acknowledge coopetition as a complex and dynamic phenomenon (Padula, Dagnino, 2007). Importantly for this study, coopetition is being increasingly popular among scholars and managers because it takes account of real-life complexity in inter-firm relationships and expands the strategist's view beyond a single firm scope (Brandenburger, Nalebuff, 1996). Table 1 illustrates the increasing number of coopetition published work ranked in the Social Sciences Citation Index (SSCI) related to strategy and management. 123 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI Table 1. Coopetition research publication dynamics Year 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Number of papers published 1 1 2 2 2 3 5 5 3 5 14 14 17 25 The selection of published work for our study consisted of three phases (Tranfield et al., 2003). Firstly, we identified the databases that hold comprehensive citation lists for management and strategy: Ebsco, Elsevier/Springer, Emerald, Proquest, and ISI Web of Knowledge. Secondly, we searched the databases for coopetition studies explicitly related to business and strategy by applying a key word search: coopetition/co-opetition located in the title, abstract or key words of papers published in English from 1997 to 2010. The use of different orthography appeared necessary, as there is still no consensus around the spelling, and authors use both. Thirdly, we have excluded papers which limited the use of coopetition to the keyword, but did not refer explicitly to the concept or did not investigate it further. We have also excluded book reviews and editorial introductions from the initial database, as well as duplicate papers appearing in the databases. Finally, we restricted the study to work published in English, even though a substantial literature is available in French, Spanish, Polish or other European languages. Table 2. Three-phase selection used in the research Selection criteria I selection II selection III selection 124 identified papers on coopetition English and full text papers supplemented with additional articles from the external databases exclude duplicate papers coopetition issues as a leading research problem extensively described issues of coopetition sector approach of the empirical research Number of papers 523 245 167 106 96 82 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… Thus, from an initial dataset of 523 papers we retained 96 for our study, while for 82 a clear industry focus could have been identified (Table 2). In order to triangulate these results the selection procedure has been conducted independently by another researcher. Coopetition has been particularly studied by European scholars, as 2/3 of published work is affiliated to European research institutions. American papers, come second with 24% followed by Asia was 9%, and Australia just 1% of all the published papers. Figure 1. Geographical distribution of coopetition papers affiliation 70% percentage of the total number of paper 60% 50% 40% 2010-01.2011 2005-2009 30% 2000-2004 1995-1999 20% 10% 0% Asia Australia Europe North America geographical region A forward citation analysis allows to identify the most cited papers, and definitions adopted by researchers (Table 3). While most papers come from the EU, the top 5 papers in terms of citation display US affiliations, with the notable Scandinavian exception (Bengtsson, Kock, 2000). The citation analysis mitigates frequency analysis results. While European publications dominate in number, they appear as less influential in the field. Also, the number of coopetition publications remains quite limited in the top journals. Table 3. Top 5 cited papers and related views on coopetition nature Authors Year published Number of citations Coopetition definition 1 2 3 4 Tsai 2002 145 simultaneously cooperative and competitive behaviour Gnyawali, Madhavan 2001 117 the relevant network consisting of formalized cooperative relationships among competitors that involve flows of assets, information and status 125 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI table 3. cont. 1 2 3 4 Bengtsson, Kock 2000 82 This relationship can include both economic and non-economic exchanges. Power in the cooperative side of the relationship is based on functional aspects in accordance with the value chain. In the competitive side of the relationship, power is based on the actor's position and strength. Luo, Slotegraaf, Pan 2006 28 Joint occurrence of cooperation and competition across functional areas within a firm Levy, Loebbecke, Powell 2003 21 Simultaneous cooperation and competition may aid competitiveness by knowledge sharing, but any exchanged knowledge may be used for competition. 2. Coopetition – a multifaceted concept 2.1. Coopetition term provenience The etymology of the term coopetition refers to competition and cooperation appearing in the same time between the same actors. The literature widely locates its origins in the 1990' when R. Noorda a former CEO of Novell (Padula, Dagnino, 2007) used it to grasp the nature of relationships between competitors. Others trace it back to 1913 (Cherington, 1976) when Kirk S. Pickett, who used it to describe the relationships among his 35,000 oyster dealers, stated: “You are only one of several dealers selling our oysters in your city. But you are not in competition with one another. You are co-operating with one another to develop more business for each of you. You are in co-opetition, not in competition”. Then R. Hunt reintroduced “co-opetition” in the Los Angeles Times in 1937, but none of these early introductions received any public attention (Hunt, 1937; Yami, Le Roy, 2010). In the management literature A. Brandenburger and B. Nalebuff (1996) have popularized coopetition. They claimed it to be more than a linguistic blend of cooperation and competition. Inversely, coopetition is to be seen as a new mindset, a process, or a phenomenon combining cooperation in order to create a bigger business pie, while competing to divide it up (Brandenburger, Nalebuff, 1996). Importantly the term coopetition has been coined by managers, which indicates an empirically grounded need to grasp the complexity of real life relationships between firms in an comprehensive way, beyond competition or collaboration alone. 126 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… 2.2. Elementary facets of coopetition We have conducted a frequency analysis in order to identify the most popular facets of coopetition and provide a synthetic view. We focused on coopetition definitions adopted in the papers. Authors’s descriptions allowed us to identify the features of coopetition, and coded them. This part of our analysis was conducted by two researchers separately. Finally, the frequency analysis was conducted. In result, we have identified six distinctive features attributed to coopetition. Interestingly all 136 authors of the 96 papers we analysed unanimously recognized (1) simultaneous cooperation and competition, and (2) mutual benefits stemming from coopetition, as the key characteristics of the phenomenon of coopetition. Authors also referred to additional features such as: (3) complexity with 57% of indications, (4) dynamics with 47%, and (5) managerial challenges scoring 46%. Finally, 28% of the authors identified (6) industry reshaping as a trait of coopetition (Figure 2). dimension of coopetition Figure 2. Coopetition concept features frequency distribution simultaneousness 100% mutual benefit 100% complexity 57% variability 47% managerial challenges industry reshaping 46% 28% percentage of authors' indications The frequency analysis allows to draw a generally accepted definition of coopetition, focused on the key traits of a distinct class of phenomena. We believe that our systematic literature review justifies the claim that coopetition is a mutually beneficial for involved actors, simultaneous cooperation and competition interplay. Our data indicate a shared view of researchers that coopetition is ontologically distinct through these two features, which are not found in any other concept. It clearly delineates coopetition from other types of interorganizational relationships. We discuss each feature appearing in the literature below. 127 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI A fundamental feature of coopetition is the simultaneity of competitive and cooperative relations between actors (Luo, 2007). Coopetition is therefore distinct from sequential cooperation and competition, where one relationship follows the other between the same firms, but not in the same time. Consequently, the study of horizontal relations between coopetitors dominate in number of papers, achieving 74% of the total. Just 14% deal with vertical relations. This stands in contradiction to M. Galvagno and F. Garraffo (2010), who claim that “most research and theory building on coopetition has focused on vertical relationships among firms (that is, channel relationships), ignoring horizontal relationships (that is, direct competitors)”. Figure 3. Type of coopetition under study percentage of the total numer of research studies 120% 100% 80% 60% horizontal vertical 40% horizontal/vertical 20% 0% period Extant research suggest that the competitive and collaborative behaviors strongly impact each other (Mariani, 2007; Tidstrom, 2008). For instance, the upsurge of competition within a collaborative agreement alters the relationship 128 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… and hampers its performance. Similarly, fostering collaboration within competitive relationships alters market structure and provides advantages to competitors. These influences follow each other. Untangling the reciprocal influence requires a process approach, event story building and path identification. The aim of coopetition is to provide benefits for all actors involved. Most frequently, through pooling resources competitors are able to achieve a competitive advantage over other market actors (e.g. Bengtsson, Kock, 2000, p. 424; Wang, Krakover, 2008, p. 128; Walley, 2007, p. 17; Luo, 2007, p. 130). “Coopetition emphasizes the mixed-motive nature of relationships in which two or more parties can create value by complementing each other’s activity” (Bonel, Rocco 2007, p. 71). Beyond the synergistic use of resources and complementarity advantages, restricted access to resources provides coopetitors with an edge over other market players. The strategic behavior of coopeting firms is oriented both at the advantages of stimulating competition and complementary resources access through cooperation (Robert, Marques, Le Roy, 2007). This facet of coopetition captures rent maximization by managers who basically want to 'have the cake and eat the cake' at the same time. Game theory offers theoretical explanations that a repeated game can provide better yields for players if they exchange information and align behaviors (Okura, 2007). While researchers provide theoretical insights and empirical evidence on how coopetition generates value, the rent appropriation process remains relatively underexplored. Few studies (Bonel, Pellizzari, Rocco, 2008) have explored the risks rising from coopetitive relationships. Yet, it holds promise of a better understanding of the phenomenon. There is a clear gap in our understanding on why coopetition is stable over time between the same actors despite rent appropriation related tensions, typical to interorganizational relationships. Researchers have recognized in more than half of published work that “coopetition strategy is a multidimensional and multifaceted concept that assumes a number of different forms and requires multiple levels of analysis”. (Chin, Chan, Lam, 2008). Therefore, different levels of analysis can be identified in the literature: network (Gnyawali, Madhavan, 2001), supply chains and value networks (Peng, Bourne, 2009), firms level for direct competitors (LeTourneau, 2004), and groups/departments/subsidiaries (Tsai, 2002) for firms. There is also a distinction of internal coopetition, within business ecosystems, versus external, which occurs between business ecosystems (Gueguen, 2009). A clear majority of existing research is focused on the interorganizational level of analysis achieving 73% of analyzed papers, while dyadic relations are introduced in 42% of the total. Both of them are also divided into simple or 129 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI complex relations (Padula, Dagnino, 2007; Robert, Marques, Le Roy, 2009). Inversely, network level studies, as well as firm level studies remain relatively few. This leaves network roles, the impact of interfirm linkages structures or processes beyond the scope of understanding. Also, intrafirm issues such as capabilities (Quintana-García, Benavides-Velasco, 2004), systems (Levy, Loebbecke, Powell, 2003) or communication are relatively underexplored. Interestingly coopetition has been found at different levels of analysis, which suggests it is disconnected from any particular type of relationship. This manifestation at various levels makes coopetition a phenomenon, much more than just a relationship feature. Coopetition relations are by nature constantly evolving, which generates a significant interest in coopetition dynamics. This concerns both the intensity of coopetition relationships and the length of period for which they are concluded. The market environment in which firms operate has significant impact on coopetition dynamics (Rusko, 2011; Luo, 2007). “[…] the content of a relationship can change from competition at one point of time, to cooperation, or coexistence, or co-opetition at another. Moreover, some relationships can grow stronger, leading to a termination of weaker relationships” (Bengtsson, Kock, 1999). The literature often labels coopetition as paradoxical (Lado, Boyd, Hanlon, 1997). Much more than a dialectical perspective of opposing forces balance or coincidentia oppositorum (Padula, Dagnino, 2007), paradoxes refer to understanding what the equilibrium really is, and call for a clear identification of the many different forces which may impact coopetition. The equilibrium approach resides on an ideal state of relations between actors, in spite of forces impacting on them. In fact “theorist focus on equilibrium arguments in order to more fully understand the dynamics of systems that are not in equilibrium” (Barney, 2001). For instance, the initially proposed nature of coopetition generates positive-sum games for firms (Brandenburger, Nalebuff, 1996). Theoretical models offer ideal-type behaviors, allowing for empirical studies to unveil why this ideal equilibrium is not achieved (Okura, 2008), as well as descriptive empirical studies which exemplify success stories of coopetitive action (Gueguen, 2009). In sum, this approach assumes a predefined, or anticipated equilibrium which is compared to actual interorganizational relationship dynamics. Interestingly, 23% of papers in our study highlight relationship dominance within coopetition. No balance between competition and cooperation is implied, be it in terms of intensity or magnitude. Notably coopetition has been categorized as: (a) cooperation-dominated relationship, (b) equal relationship, (c) competition-dominated relationship (Bengtsson, Kock, 2000; Rusko, 2011). Ritala, 130 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… Hallikas and Sissonen (2008) name them as intensive competition coopetition or intensive cooperation coopetition. Luo (2005) expands this typology by adding to dominated relationships two types of balanced ones: low-low and high-high intensity of collaboration and competition (Table 4). Table 4. Coopetition types regarding relationships intensity and balance Collaboration Competition high low high high intensity coopetition competition dominated low cooperation dominated low intensity coopetition This simple classification of possible coopetition types calls for more detailed studies. One thread of research should focus on the relationship intensity. Beyond a measurement challenge, more intermediate intensity degrees can be identified: medium, semi-strong and so on. As a result the typology matrix would expand to cover nine, sixteen or more theoretical coopetition manifestations, to be further empirically examined. A second thread of further scrutiny needs to explore coopetition stability issue over time. While equilibrium perspective appears as useful for balanced (hi-hi or low-low) coopetition studies, there is a gap in our understanding of unbalanced relationships. Dialectical perspective would suggest them to be inherently unstable or short-term, but empirical evidence shows that firms may remain in unbalanced or dominated coopetition for extended periods of time. The nature of coopetition is reflected in considerable managerial challenges that coopetitors have to face in order to succeed. Researchers (Zineldin, 1998) underline that adequate competence and ambidexterity of the management team are key factors in the success of a coopetition strategy. “Co-opetition involves two different logics of interaction. On the one hand, there is a hostility due to conflicting interests and, on the other hand, it is necessary to develop trust and mutual commitment to achieve common aims” (Quintana-García, Benavides-Velasco, 2004). Moreover, some authors add a high level of managerial involvement in the process of the preparation, implementation and coordination of the coopetition as equally important factors in the success. What seems to be undervalued here is the matter of trust between cooperating competitors. Despite their long-term habits, on the one hand managers have to make room for cooperative relations which, without trust and a general positive atmosphere, cannot exist, while on the other they have to know the lines that they cannot cross as regards the close- 131 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI ness of the relationship (e.g. protection of trade secrets) (Chin, Chan, Lam, 2008). Similarly to firm level studies, managerial challenges address the relevance of coopetition research in terms of success or failure factors. While theoretical directions of scrutiny have been indicated in the literature, empirical studies remain few. While coopetition has originally been related to the value creating network (Brandenburger, Nalebuff, 1996), only a limited number of papers address this feature. Coopetition strategies are used by firms in response to increasing environment volatility (Baumard, 2009). Also, if a firm creates coopetitive relations, others imitate this strategy. Similarly, market/industry regulations, customs, or the environment can push market participants to launch coopetition strategies (Mariani, 2007; Zineldin, 1998). Thus, industry reshaping is characterizes coopetition: “managers must monitor and analyze environmental changes to assess the need to engage in co-opetition, and if co-opetition is intensifying in the industry, they should explicitly consider competitors when pursuing technology intensive alliances” (Gnyawali, Park, 2009). The creation of a new industry structure, either by including complementors or by reshaping the inter-firm relationships is theoretically a feature of coopetition. However, very few studies adopt industry level of analysis, leaving this particular coopetition feature underexplored. 3. Theoretical lenses for coopetition studies Emerging research threads typically exploit more established theoretical frameworks. Drawing heavily on related fields might be a ‘Faustian bargain’, “if a research community fails to estimate the consequences of becoming too bound with related fields” (Agarwal, Hoetker, 2007). We examine in this section the links of coopetition studies with theoretical frameworks addressing relationships between firms. We extend prior research on interorganizational literature (Oliver, Ebers, 1998) by analyzing how coopetition studies exploit theoretical references. The distribution of underpinning theoretical perspectives, according to what authors themselves claim is illustrated in Table 5. Table 5. Coopetition theoretical background Background % of articles Game Theory Alliances TCE RBV Networks Competition Evolutionary Economics Other 39% 83% 8% 35% 23% 24% 9% 3% Note: The sum exceeds 100% as authors typically use more than one theoretical framework in their studies. 132 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… A closer analysis of the theoretical frameworks adopted by authors shows that three perspectives are prevailing: alliances, competition and network theory. We devote less attention to the resource based view and to game theory, as authors use those reference frameworks as auxiliary. More specifically resource based rationale is mostly deployed to justify interorganizational relationship formation and competitive advantage achievement. Game theory in turn provides a strong rational choice assumption to model collaboration between rivals as the best strategic option. 3.1. Alliances perspective on coopetition The alliances literature appears a prevailing background, scoring more than 83% of all studies. Alliances are defined as voluntary arrangements between firms involving exchange, sharing or co-development of products, technologies or services (Gulati, 1998). The body of alliances literature focuses on: the formation rationale, the dynamics, and the outcomes – specifically performance of alliances and involved firms (Oliver, Ebers, 1998). Coopetition research can be analyzed along those axes. The literature provides several explanations for coopetition use by firms, such as resource access, joint resource exploitation or competitive pressures. There is evidence of positive relationship between coopetitive strategies in jointly bidding for resources and financial performance (Robert, Marques, Le Roy, 2009). An empirical study of the soft drink industry promotions shows that brand interdependence shapes market structure. Strong bottlers’ promotions allow to increase a relative market share of the promoted brand, and at the same time to increase the relative market share of strong bottlers at the expense of weak bottlers (Meade, Hyman, Blank, 2009). Technology development in the LCD panel industry has proven to yield for collaborating competitors: Sony and Samsung. Their combined market share has risen from challengers into market leaders thanks to coopetition in R&D (Gnyawali, Park, 2011). The view that coopetition focuses on the interplay between cooperative and competitive actions of the value network members implies a dynamic approach and encourages the study of development patterns. Two distinct epistemological stances are widespread in management studies for elucidating dynamic phenomena: equilibrium, and evolutionary theories (Barney, 2001). Equilibrium stance has been described in detail in Section 2.2. The evolutionary approach to coopetition dynamics study adopts a different view, aiming at identifying patterns of change. Extant research has unveiled 133 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI evolutionary patterns in coopetitive relationships: a) deliberate development characterized by intentional rent seeking at both individual and collective level, where coopetitor’s actions are relatively clear or even announced; b) emerging, which refer to the upsurge of unilateral rent seeking behaviors within cooperative settings, mostly unplanned before the cooperation start. Figure 4. Coopetition strategy development patterns deliberate (Robert, Marques, Le Roy, 2009; Meade, Hyman, Blank, 2009) coopetition patterns emerging (Mariani, 2007; Tidstrom, 2008; Czakon, 2009) The deliberate thread of research suggests that coopetition is a strategy aiming at above average earnings. Typically those are referred to as competitive advantage, yet studies provide evidence that focal actors performance improve whenever competitors are able to generate positive interdependency. The second patterns of coopetition between firms is emergence. Development paths identification uses longitudinal case studies unveiling series of events. Under this assumption competition emerges between partners when cooperative relationships are subject to tensions, conflict or discrepancies. There is evidence that cooperation can be imposed on otherwise competing actors by the institutional environment, such as a policy maker (Mariani, 2007). Actors find themselves strongly encouraged to forge a more cooperative value chain model, where resources and information are better shared. Inversely, there is also evidence that power asymmetries and unfair value distribution among actors, may lead to the emergence of competition within a cooperative framework, as shown in two Finnish industries: transportation and natural product (Tidström, 2008), and the Polish banking franchise system case (Czakon, 2009). The starting point of those empirical studies is a cooperative settings, where opportunism, conflict 134 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… or instabilities emerge. So far deliberate and emerging paths have been scrutinized, both from competitive and cooperative starting points which allows for a matrix typology of coopetitive behaviors along those two axes (table 6). Table 6. Coopetition strategies empirical typology Development path Deliberate Emerging Starting point Competitive Ó collective competition against others, Ó collective resource acquisition Ó induced cooperation, Ó resource sharing, Ó cooperative value chain model Cooperative Ó competition for the “share in the pie”, Ó value sharing agreement, Ó rent appropriation Ó opportunism, Ó conflict, Ó unilateral rent seeking Coopetition outcomes have mostly been scrutinized from firm-level perspective, with some notable interorganizational level exceptions. At firm level there is growing evidence that coopetition fosters innovativeness and technology development (Ritala, 2011). Also, firms entering coopetitive relationships may expect positive market performance impact (Meade, Hyman, Bank, 2009; Gnyawali, Park, 2009), as coordinated action provides an edge over other firms. The impact of coopetition strategies on financial performance has been found positive (Robert, Marques, Le Roy, 2009), yet other studies suggest that it is limited or even absent depending on the number of coopetitors (Ritala, Hallikas, Sissonen, 2008). While firm level impact is generally positive with some ambiguities, the collective level of analyses has been used much less frequently. There is a gap in the literature referring to what we call ‘the coopetitive advantage’, a clear benefit arising from coopetitive relationships. 3.2. Competition perspective on coopetition Competition frameworks come second in reference frequency with 24% of papers. Competitive relationships exist when firms seek out the same limited resources, or target the same market or customers (Gimeno, 2004). If competition arises from niche overlap, then coopetition studies examine the extent and the impact of this overlap (Kotzab, Keller, 2003). Studies referring to competition perspective display a less structured use of competition theory, than those 135 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI which refer to alliances. Instead of mobilizing a theoretical framework researchers rather use some concepts, such as: competitive manoeuvring, competitive advantage, value chain, and exploit game theoretical explanations (Brandenburger, Nalebuff, 1996; Rusko, 2011). Competitive manoeuvring explores how intercompetitor dynamics intensity impact rivals and firms performance. Similarly, coopetition studies show that competitive advantage captures above average earnings achieved by one firm against its competitors. A restrained use of competition may be linked to their narrow focus on one type of relationship between firms. The rise of alliances in management literature has primarily been a reaction to this argument. Several studies show coopetition to be a successful strategy when applied by firms to individual value chain activities: procurement, marketing or R&D. Firms are involved in various interorganizational relationships with others along the value chain in the same time (Solitander, Tidström, 2010). Bengtsson and Kock (2000) have shown that firms tend to cooperate within activities that are more far away from the customer, while they compete within activities closer to the customer. Some studies explore: a) upstream coopetitive activities: R&D, buying, processing of raw materials; b) downstream coopetitive activities – distribution, services marketing (Bengtsson, Kock, 2003; Rusko, 2011), and Mariani (2007) adds the midstream aspect – production. Coopetition is simultaneously cooperating and competing, but on different activities (Bengtsson, Eriksson, Wincent, 2010). Two or more competitors can cooperate in product development or technology upgrades and at the same time compete in taking orders, attracting customers, or expanding market share (Gnyawali, Madhavan, 2001; Tsai, 2002). The separation of activities that are jointly carried out from those, which are individually operated by firms contributes to alleviate tensions between collaborative and competitive logic. Therefore a clear thread of research is opened for further coopetition studies, focusing on each and every activity along the value chain: logistics, operations, human resource or even firm infrastructure. 3.3. Network perspective The network approach is referred to in 23% of papers. A distinctive feature of network studies is that firm performance is dependent on whom interacts with whom (Håkansson, Snehota, 2006). In other words the organization-environment interface can be scrutinized along network structures, positions and roles played by actors involved. We combine it with evolutionary economics because both approaches adopt a collective level of analysis and use either structural variables or descriptive dynamics (Luo, 2005; Czakon, 2009; Bengtsson, Kock, 1999). 136 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… Interestingly network related issues, such as ecosystem competition or internal dynamics leading to coopetition strategies have been relatively popular among scholars (Chien, Peng, 2002; Gueguen, 2009; M’Chirgui, 2005). A majority of the existing research is focused on the network perspective of coopetition (41%), while dyadic relations are introduced in 7% of the total. Interestingly, a substantial number of papers has opted for the interorganizational level of analysis, which is broader than a dyad, but still not a network. Those studies account for roughly half the sample (49%). Networks are assumed to consist of participants trying to achieve common benefits, whether they are internal value networks (organizations) or networks between different organizations (Solitander, Tidström, 2010). Firms in networks develop a set of relationships through connected activities, linked resources and related actors, all of these elements being interconnected and interdependent. Researchers focus on the roles of the participants involved in the relations (Table 7). Theoretical models suggest that coopetitors can have different roles within value networks. Yet, there is very few empirical studies examining them in detail. Notably, recent empirical evidence shows that third-party actors may have an enabling role in coopetition (Castaldo et al., 2010). A more detailed identification of coopetition network roles and their impact on the coopetition process is therefore necessary. Table 7. Roles in Network Coopetition – some examples Source Chin, Chan, Lam, 2008 Luo, 2007 Rusko, 2011; Bengtsson, Eriksson, Wincent, 2010 Chien, Peng, 2005 Luo, 2005 Identified roles in network coopetition contender, adapter, monoplayer, partner estranger, contender, partner, and integrator competitors, complementors, suppliers, and customers direct & indirect partners, current or potential competitors aggressive demander, silent implementer, ardent contributor, network captain Future research should undertake the challenge of studying the relationship between network structural variables: density, betweenness, centrality or size and coopetition. Also roles played in networks have impact on coopetition which still calls for empirical investigation. A diverse theoretical background suggests that coopetition has not been scrutinized in a consistent way. Consequently, the research findings might be difficult to integrate into a coherent body of knowledge. Similarly to the interorganizational dynamics literature (Bell, Den Ouden, Ziggers, 2006), com- 137 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI peting hypotheses arise from a rapidly growing body of empirical findings. Yet, those findings are drawn from various paradigms and therefore cannot be directly confronted in terms of better explanatory power. There is a growing need to develop a more coherent theory of coopetition. 4. Empirical research foci Recently a substantial increase in coopetition empirical studies number can be noticed, bringing rich insights into the phenomenon. Using frequency analysis we identify coopetition research by sector, semi-sector and industry (Figure 5). Figure 5. Semi-sectors in papers over time manufacturing information and communication (ICT) human health and social work activities financial and insurance activities arts, entertainment and recreation semi-sector wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles years 1995-1999 administrative and support service activities 2000-2004 2005-2009 transportation and storage 2010-01.2011 construction agriculture, forestry and fishing professional, scientific and technical activities public administration and defence; compulsory social security education 0% 5% 10% 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% percentage of the total number of papers 40% Firstly, following C. Clark and J. Fourastie, we distinguish three economic sectors (Wolfe, 1955): agriculture, manufacturing, and services. For detailed analyses, the European statistical classification NACE Rev2 has been adopted: it specifies of 21 types of economic activity, which are henceforth called semi- 138 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… sectors (Eurostat, 2011). 72 papers have been identified in accordance with our classification. Additionally, the High-Tech semi-sector has been added, classified in accordance with the product method of the classification of High-Tech goods by the OECD. A substantial attention is paid to services sector, which was dealt with by a total of 58% of research. Industry comes next with 39% of published work, while agriculture is last, capturing a marginal attention of 3%. An imbalance in the research also emerged inside each sector, where extremely different proportions fall to particular semi-sectors, and strong variations of academic interest can be observed over time. In the case of the first sector, half of the papers concern forestry (50%) and the second one fishing (50%). In the second sector, a vast majority was focused on manufacturing (93%), with just 7% dealing with construction. Research in the third sector was dominated by the ICT semi-sector (26%) and human health and social work activities (14%). A scant number of analyses concern activities relating to education and widely defined public administration. Similarly, the High-Tech semi-sector receives the most of academic attention in coopetition studies with a total of 33% of published work (Figure 6). Within high-technology, the most frequent research subject was ICT economic activity (this represents 46% of the total number of papers) and then aviation industry (13%). Pharmaceutical, chemical and biotechnological spheres were less explored by scientists. Nevertheless, the High-Tech semi-sector with a result of 33% of the research has been the most scientifically explored business activity so far. Figure 6. High-Technology industries in papers ICT aviation branch NDA defense electronic biotechnological chemical advanced materials 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% percentage of the total number of papers 139 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI To summarise, coopetition appears here as an industry related phenomenon, especially concerned with complex products, rapid technology change (Ritala, 2011), intensive competition (Robert, Marques, Le Roy, 2009), and high uncertainty (Gnyawali, Park, 2009). Yet, there is a visible failure to address more established industries, or less dynamic sectors of activity. Researchers so far opted for sharply observable empirical settings leaving a substantial part of businesses beyond focus. Further research needs to take an increasingly detailed account of the context, and by expanding the focus of interest onto industries so far under-researched. 5. Discussion and implications for further research Our study shows that coopetition is perceived by scholars as a novel object of study. The rising interest in tackling coopetition displays a surge in total number of studies, and more recently of empirical papers. For a century this phenomenon labelled by managers did not attract academic attention, then for a decade since its introduction in the literature it has been of interest for a restricted community of researchers. Yet, if the current trend would be sustained, coopetition has all chances to go beyond a community of researchers into a key issue in management (Figure 7). Figure 7. Estimated increase in number of papers on coopetition 450 400 y = 0.006x4 - 0.097x3 + 0.712x2 - 0.274x + 0.508 R² = 0.998 350 no. of papers 300 250 200 150 R² = 0,9986 100 50 cumulative number of all the papers empirical papers conceptual papers projected trend of the delta of all the papers projected trend - empirical papers projected trend - conceptual papers Source: Based on M. Rogalski (2011). 140 year 2015 2014 2013 2012 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 -50 2011 R² = 0,9821 0 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… Most of expected growth should be attributable to empirical papers, where authors refer to clearly defined features of coopetition. The upsurge of empirical work and relative decrease in theoretical frameworks suggest a widespread adoption of a grounded theory approach. Fragmentation and growing detail in studies comes into light. Further insights will strongly be dependent on whether authors opt for convergent theoretical stances, and thus avoid the pitfall of paradigmatic tensions, or not. Our study suggests that the prolific heterogeneity reported in empirical studies has not unveiled any clear morphology of coopetition so far. While a common understanding of what coopetition is clearly emerges in the literature, researchers have failed so far to provide a detailed picture of the different forms coopetition may take. One reason might be that coopetition is more a principle for human action than a strategy. Theory building subsequent effort shall take account of different coopetition contingencies, which suggests that formulating a set of principles for coopeting could be a valuable starting point (Chin, Chan and Lam 2007). The other reason might be connected with the need to expand the empirical body of literature. For this effort to be fruitful to the discipline, some basic lines of further inquiry should be drawn. A few key issues remain out of coopetition studies scope, although in related fields those concerns have been investigated. This refers to the reasons: a) why a firm does have ambiguous and opposing behaviors? b) what makes managers so willing to act for the sake of others in complex and risky ways? and c) what makes competitive and cooperative rents achievable in the long run? We organize further research agenda following Oliver and Ebers (1998) in order to address those questions in Table 8. It allows both to extend current research threads by filling existing gaps, and develop some research foci so far missing in the literature. Table 8. Further research agenda antecedents – processes – outcomes Theoretical challenge 1 Antecedents Research question Observation needs 2 3 Need for an evaluation of factors which make coopetition a first choice strategy, or more likely to appear in specific settings. Need to observe life cycle dependencies of interfirm coopetitive relationships What exogenous factors induce or facilitate coopetition? What endogenous factors or propensities facilitate coopetition? How do factors impact coopetition behaviors? 141 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI table 8 cont. 1 2 Process What coordination mechanisms contribute to coopetition success? What is the morphology of a coopetition process? What capabilities need to be mobilized for successful coopetition? Why is coopetition stable over time? How does the coopetition process unfold over time? Outcomes What advantages come from bringing together competition and collaboration? How to operationalise rents arising from coopetition? How does coopetition impact performance, innovation or survival? 3 Need to identify and evaluate governance forms and leadership roles in coopetition behaviors. Need to identify the sequences of events that intertwine collaboration with competition, as patterns. Need to explore the dynamics and balance within coopetition. Need to discern coopetition development patterns Need to identify and evaluate rents attributable to coopetition. Need to observe the extent to which coopetition is difficult to imitate, in sustainable advantage terms. Need to examine the strength and shape of the relationship between coopetition and dependent variables However up-to-date empirical investigation of coopetition antecedents has so far been fragmented and descriptive, it has also the merit to open ways for more articulate and systematic scrutiny. Industry related antecedents have been outlined only very recently (Ritala, 2011), while the size of firms has been brought only a few years earlier (Gnyawali, Park, 2001). In other words some exogenous factors inciting managers to adopt coopetition have been examined. Empirical evidence shows the pivotal role of regulatory bodies in adopting coopetition in health care (Barretta, 2008). Further research can be expected to deeper analyze such exogenous factors as deregulation (Depeyre, Dumez, 2010), globalization (Luo, 2004) or social networks. One of key questions within coopetition research is whether the rationale for anti-competitive legislation is still valid. The regulators have long been assuming so far that any form of collaboration between competitors is anti-competitive, collusive and harmful for the customer (Vonortas, 2000). Coopetition as a revolutionary mindset (Brandenburger, Nalebuff, 1996) and the value network concept bring positive-sum into the competitive game, which stands in opposition with the traditional view. This calls for research on the impact of regulation and deregulation on coopetition adoption by firms. Globalization in turn brings an increased competitive pressure, which may induce firms into coopetition as a response to perceived external threats. Similarly, social networks can convey mimetic pressures between managers, which otherwise would not be adopted. All in all, extant research suggests that 142 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… coopetition is adopted as a reaction to external stimuli, but the list of those exogenous factors is far from being exhaustive. Also, endogenous factors require further attention. More commonly resource or capability contingencies have been examined in the perspective or resource interdependency of firms (Mariani, 2007). There is a substantial literature explaining why competitors collaborate, but it still fails to address the question why all competitors do not collaborate? Other endogenous factors such as: managerial propensities for individual or collective action, corporate level strategies, communication issues can shed more light on coopetition. Compared to antecedents, the coopetition process is far better understood. However, the majority of authors use alliance references. This raises a key question on how different coopetition is from alliances? The epistemological assumptions are clearly different. While competition, tension or instabilities in alliances literature are considered as nuisance and source of concern (Das, Teng, 2000), within coopetition studies they are sources of success. When a tension appears in the time span of a collaborative agreement in the alliances literature, this very coincidence of competition and collaboration consumes the whole time span of coopetition studies. If alliances consider a single, ideal-type relationship at a time and observe its morphology empirically, coopetition studies deliberately opt for a complex, dialectical and holistic approach to consider a real life phenomenon and draw propositions from the business reality. Also, the alliance literature on competitor collaboration is ambiguous. Indeed prior studies show high failure rates which might lead to zero or even negative-sum games (Ritala, 2011). For instance, direct competitor alliances in the airline industry studies provide negative evidence on effectiveness (Gimeno, 2004). In our view, the synchronicity, ontological and epistemological stances clearly differentiate coopetition from alliances. Coopetition manifestations differ across industries, levels of analysis and scope of study. Within such a variety a more systematic recognition of distinct types has been missing so far. We believe that coopetition typologies constitute a promising thread of study. Theoretical typologies, based for instance on the collaboration and competition relative intensity would unveil a set of ideal types. Further empirical scrutiny would confirm that firms adopt them, or fail to. The degree of intensity has also the merit to open ways for a detailed examination of internal balance and dynamics within coopetition. Nevertheless the majority of literature adopted an interorganizational level of analysis has become the preferred level of scrutiny. Inversely, firm or activity level considerations are relatively under researched. This opens ways for inves- 143 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI tigating both coopetition for each and every single value chain activity firms carry out, but also articulations between cooperation on some activities while competing on others. Managerial ambidexterity is to be found at this level of analysis, as a critical success factor for coopetition. Ambidexterity refers to the capability of organizations to simultaneously manage opposite competencies. Initially ambidexterity has been introduced to capture the capability to explore and exploit knowledge (Raich et al., 2009). A very similar challenge emerges when firms are engaged in coopetition, as they need to display the capability to manage competitive and collaborative behaviors (Herzog, 2010). Ambidexterity raises the issue of developing different or opposite capabilities, and to handle the tensions arising from its difference. Therefore, studies which focus on capabilities required to successfully coopete may shed light on factors fostering coopetition process. Similarly, network level or industry level empirical studies are still few. This level of analysis takes account of market structure contingencies, ecosystems competition, collective growth strategies, etc. Therefore coopetitive dynamics for competing ecosystems yield promise of providing important insights. Networks imply various roles played by firms. The literature has very seldom used structural variables to explain coopetition or even to identify it. A clear methodological gap emerges here as far as the use of social network analysis techniques is concerned. Finally, coopetition outcomes have so far been examined for a limited number of variables. Innovation performance (Quintara-Garcia, Benavides-Velasco, 1996), market performance (Meade, Hyman, Blank, 2009) and financial performance (Ritala, Hallikas, Sissonen, 2008) have been frequently used as outcome variables to demonstrate, that coopetition strategies are beneficial for the firm. However, those studies provide ambiguous results suggesting different impact depending on the number of coopetitors. Empirical evidence unveils mediating variables between coopetition strategies and financial performance, such as market learning (Luo, Slotegraaf, Pan, 2006) or efficient consumer response (Kotzab, Keller, 2003). Prior findings encourages replication or larger sample studies in order to confirm the positive impact and explore boundary conditions, such as the size of firms involved, their heterogeneity, technology life cycles, etc. Also, it seems useful to explore how coopetition can impact outcomes of interest at different levels of management: market share, risk or entry for functional strategists; performance for business unit managers; growth or profitability for corporate level managers. The paradoxical nature of coopetition, coupled with ambiguous results of performance studies suggests, that the role of coopetition may be different across the firm. Further on, we can test the hypothesis that for some activities coopetition is advisable, while for others it offers less interesting results (Bengtsson, Kock, 2000). 144 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… Similarly, there is few evidence on how coopetition is beneficial for the whole value network. Firm level studies provide insights into how one coopetitor can take advantage of collaborative rents. Thus, researchers address the question why one firm should use coopetition, but fail to address the question why others should follow. In other words, beyond sharp examples of focal firm success, more attention is required to show how coopetition generates common benefits available to all coopetitors. Such studies would aim at isolating the value generated by coopetition for businesses, as a parallel to competitive advantage (Barney, 2001) or collaborative advantage (Dyer, Singh, 1998). If the interplay between competition and collaboration is constitutive for coopetition, then we can expect that the coopetition rent is more than the sum of competitive advantage and collaborative rents. Importantly coopetition has so far been considered as a behaviour of choice, and a difficult one. Should it also be difficult to imitate, then coopetitive rents would have their very high rank in strategy literature. Conclusions The founding achievement of coopetition research community is much more than coining a term for a complex phenomenon. Researchers agree on its key features, and have identified some development paths: emergent and deliberate. Some initial typologies have followed. Also, coopetition has been presented as optimal, equilibrium strategy, which facilitates the study of under-performing competitive or cooperative strategies. A systematic scrutiny of the literature sheds light on several gaps. A first general issue in coopetition research is its morphology – there is need to expand empirical research beyond high-tech industries, and examine it more in detail along the value chain activities. Secondly, further research should address the stability issue – what is the glue holding opposed or unbalanced competition and collaboration together? Exogenous pressures, separation of collaborative and competitive activities, or organizational ambidexterity hold promise of better explanations than currently available. This thread of research may shed additional light both on coopetition antecedents and on the coopetition process. Thirdly, coopetition outcomes need to be brought into light – what is in it for participating firms? Beyond innovation, market and financial performance other variables such as growth, survival or speed to marked can be explored. Future research may also isolate the coopetitive advantage, both as common and appropriable benefit. 145 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI Coopetition remains of high managerial relevance and draws rapidly growing academic attention. However, it is still more of a recognized concept than a theory, which can mostly be attributed to the early stage of research. For example, alliances investigation started in early 1980's and brought in a consistent and seminal body of research in late 1990's and so forth. By analogy, coopetition would need about 10 years more to address empirical issues with a consistent theory. Providing it with theoretical grounds or at least comparatively testing available theories for heterogeneous empirical settings may be viewed as a major challenge. Rent seeking behavior seems promising, as it provides explanations for the rationale of simultaneous competitive and cooperative behaviors, for unilateral rent seeking and collective action, as well as for adaptive actions. Indeed coopetition has brought three concepts into strategy research which have long been absent from it or have been considered separately: 1) value maximization in an interorganizational context, 2) rent appropriation as a simultaneous concern, and 3) emergent adaptation to changing operation's circumstances. Given the intellectual challenge coopetition brings to researchers, and the high managerial relevance of the topic further research holds promise of gathering increasing audiences. References Agarwal R., Hoetker H. (2007): The Growth of Management and Its Relationship with Related Disciplines, “The Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 50(6), pp. 1304-1322. Barney J. (2001): Is the Resource-Based View a Useful Perspective for Strategic Management Research? Yes. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 26(1), pp. 41-56. Barretta A. (2008): The functioning of Co-opetition in the Health-Care Sector: An Explorative Analysis. “Scandinavian Journal of Management”, Vol. 24, pp. 209-220. Baumard P. (2009): An Asymmetric Perspective on Coopetitive Strategies. “International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business”, Vol. 8(1), pp. 6-22. Bell J., Den Ouden B., Ziggers G. (2006): Dynamics of Cooperation: At the Brink of Irrelevance. “Journal of Management Studies”, Vol. 43(7), pp. 1607-1619. Bengtsson M., Eriksson J., Wincent J. (2010): Coopetition: New Ideas for a New Paradigm. In: Eds. S. Yami, S. Castaldo, G.B. Dagnino and F. Le Roy: Coopetition Winning Strategies for 21st Century. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp. 19-39 Bengtsson M., Kock S. (1999): Cooperation and Competition in Relationships Between Competitors in Business Networks. “The Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing”, Vol. 14(3), pp. 178-91. 146 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… Bengtsson M., Kock S. (2000): Co-opetition in Business Networks – to Cooperate and Compete Simultaneously. “Industrial Marketing Management”, Vol. 29(5), pp. 411-426. Bonel E., Pellizzari P., Rocco E. (2008): Coopetition and Complementarities Modeling Coopetition Strategy and Its Risks at an Individual Partner Level. “Management Research”, Vol. 6(3), pp. 189-205. Bonel E., Rocco E. (2007): Coopeting to Survive; Surviving Coopetition. “International Studies of Management & Organization”, Vol. 37(2), pp. 70-96. Brandenburger A.M., Nalebuff B.J. (1996): Co-Opetition. Doubleday Currency, New York. Castaldo S., Mollering G., Grosso M., Zerbini F. (2010): Exploring How Third-Party Organizations Facilitate Coopetition Management in Buyer-Seller Relationships. In: Eds. S. Yami, S. Castaldo, G.B. Dagnino and F. Le Roy: Coopetition Winning Strategies for 21st Century. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp. 141-165. Cherington P. T. (1976): Advertising as a Business Force: A Compilation of Experiences. Reissue edition. Ayer, Manchester, NH. Chien T.H., Peng T.J. (2005): Competition and Cooperation Intensity in a Network – a Case Study in Taiwan Simulator Industry. “The Journal of American Academy of Business”. Cambridge, Vol. 7(2), pp. 150-155. Chin K.-S., Chan B.L., Lam P.-K. (2008): Identifying and Prioritizing Critical Success Factors for Coopetition Strategy. “Industrial Management & Data Systems”, Vol. 108(4), pp. 437-454. Czakon W. (2009): Power Asymmetries, Flexibility and the Propensity to Coopete: An Empirical Investigation of SMEs’ Relationships with Franchisors. “International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business”, Vol. 8(1), pp. 44-60. Das T., Teng B-S. (2000). Instabilities of Strategic Alliances: An Internal Tension Perspective. “Organization Science”, Vol. 11(1), pp. 77-101. Depeyre C., Dumez H. (2010): The Role of Architectural Players in Coopetition: the Case of the US Defense Industry. In: Eds. S. Yami, S. Castaldo, G.B. Dagnino and F. Le Roy: Coopetition Winning Strategies for 21st Century. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp. 124-140. Dyer J., Singh H. (1998): The Relational View: Cooperative Strategy and Sources of Interorganizational Competitive Advantage. “The Academy of Management Review”, Vol. 24(4), pp. 660-679. Eurostat Statistical Books (2011). Europe in Figures. Eurostat Yearbook 2011, European Union, Belgium. Galvagno M., Garraffo F. (2010): The Promise of Coopetition as a New Theoretical Perspective in Strategic Management. In: Eds. S. Yami, S. Castaldo, G.B. Dagnino and F. Le Roy: Coopetition Winning Strategies for 21st Century. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp. 40-57. 147 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI Gimeno J. (2004): Competition within and between Networks: The Contingent Effect of Competitive Embeddedness on Alliance Formation. “The Academy of Management Journal”, Vol. 47(6), pp. 820-842. Gnyawali D.R., Madhavan R. (2001): Cooperative Networks and Competitive Dynamics: A Structural Embeddedness Perspective. “The Academy of Management Review”, Vol. 26(3), pp. 431-445. Gnyawali D.R., Park B.-J.R. (2009): Co-Opetition and Technological Innovation in Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises: A Multilevel Conceptual Model. ”Journal of Small Business Management”, Vol. 47(3), pp. 308-330. Gnyawali D.R., Park B.-J.R. (2011): Co-Opetition between Giants: Collaboration with Competitors for Technological Innovation. “Research Policy”, Vol. 40(5), pp. 650-663 Gueguen G. (2009): Coopetition and Business Ecosystems in the Information Technology Sector: The Example of Intelligent Mobile Terminals. “International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business”, Vol. 8(1), pp. 135-153. Gulati R. (1998): Alliances and Networks. “Strategic Management Journal”, Vol. 19, pp. 293-317. Hakanson H., Snehota I. (1989): No Business is an Island: The Network Concept of Strategy. “Scandinavian Journal of Management”, Vol. 5, pp. 187-200 Herzog T. (2010): Strategic Management of Coopetitive Relationships in CoPS-Related Industries. In: Eds. S. Yami, S. Castaldo, G.B. Dagnino and F. Le Roy: Coopetition Winning Strategies for 21st Century. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp. 200-215. Hunt R. (1937): Co-Opetition. “Los Angeles Times”, November 20, pp. 4-9. Kotzab H., Keller, Ch. (2003): Value-Adding Partnerships and Co-opetition Models in the Grocery Industry. “International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management”, Vol. 33(3), pp. 268-281. Lado A., Boyd N., Hanlon S. (1997): Competition, Cooperation and the Search for Economic Rents: A Syncretic Model. “Academy of Management Review”, Vol. 22(1), pp. 110-141. Lee R. (2009): Social Capital and Business and Management: Setting a research agenda. “International Journal of Management Reviews”, Vol. 11, No. 3, pp. 247-273. LeTourneau B. (2004): Co-Opetition: An Alternative to Competition. “Journal of Healthcare Management”, Vol. 49(2), pp. 81-83. Levy M., Loebbecke C., Powell P. (2003): SMEs, Co-Opetition and Knowledge Sharing: the Role of Information Systems. “European Journal of Information Systems”, Vol. 12, pp. 3-17. Luo Y. (2004): A Coopetition Perspective of MNC – Host Government Relations. “Journal of International Management”, Vol. 10, pp. 431-451. 148 COOPETITION RESEARCH LANDSCAPE… Luo Y. (2005): Toward Coopetition within a Multinational Enterprise: A Perspective from Foreign Subsidiaries. “Journal of World Business”, Vol. 40, pp. 71-90. Luo Y. (2007): A Coopetition Perspective of Global Competition. “Journal of World Business”, Vol. 42, pp. 129-144. Luo Y., Slotegraaf R.J., Pan X. (2006): Cross-Functional “Coopetition”: The Simultaneous Role of Cooperation and Competition Within Firms. “Journal of Marketing”, Vol. 70, pp. 67-80. M.A. Zineldin (1998): Towards an Ecological Collaborative Relationship Management. A “Co-opetive” Perspective. “European Journal of Management”, Vol. 32(11/12), pp. 1138-1164. M’Chirgui Z. (2005): Smart Card Industry: A Technological System. “Technovation”, Vol. 25, pp. 929-938. Mariani M. (2007): Coopetition as an Emergent Strategy. Empirical Evidence from an Italian Consortium of Opera Houses. “International Studies of Management & Organization”, Vol. 37(2), pp. 97-126. Meade W., Hyman M., Blank L. (2009): Promotions as Coopetition in the Soft Drink Industry. “Academy of Marketing Studies Journal”, Vol. 13(1), pp. 105-133. Okura M. (2008): Why Isn’t the Accident Information Shared? A Coopetition Perspective. “Management Research”, Vol. 6(3), pp. 219-225. Okura,M. (2007): Strategies of Japanese Insurance Firm. A Game-Theory Approach. ”International Studies and Management & Organization”, Vol. 37(2), pp. 53-69. Oliver A., Ebers M. (1998): Networking Network Studies: an Analysis of Conceptual Configurations in the Study of Inter-Organizational Relationships. “Organization Studies”, Vol. 19(4), pp. 549-583 Padula G., Dagnino G.B. (2007): Untangling the Rise of Coopetition. The Intrusion of Competition in a Cooperative Game Structure. “International Studies and Management & Organization”, Vol. 37(2), pp. 32-52. Peng T-J.A., Bourne M. (2009) : The Coexistence of Competition and Cooperation between Networks: Implications from Two Taiwanese Healthcare Networks. ”British Journal of Management”, Vol. 20, pp. 377-400. Quintana-García C., Benavides-Velasco C.A. (2004): Cooperation, Competition, and Innovative Capability: A Panel Data of European Dedicated Biotechnology Firms. “Technovation”, Vol. 24, pp. 927-938. Raich S., Birkinshaw J., Probst G., Tushman M., (2009): Organizational Ambidexterity: Balancing Exploitation and Exploration for Sustained Performance. “Organization Science”, Vol. 20(4), pp. 685-695. Ritala P. (2011): Coopetition Strategy – When Is It Successful? Empirical Evidence on Innovation and Market Performance. “British Journal of Management”, Vol. 23(3), pp. 307-324 149 W OJCIECH C ZAKON , K AROLINA M UCHA -K UŚ , M ARIUSZ R OGALSKI Ritala P., Hallikas J., Sissonen H. (2008): The Effects of Strategic Alliances between Key Competitors on Firm Performance. “Management Research”, Vol. 6(3), pp. 179-187. Robert F., Marques P., Le Roy F. (2009): Coopetition Between SMEs: An Empirical Study of French Professional Football. “International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business”, Vol. 8(1), pp. 23-43. Rogalski M. (2011): Strategia koopetycji – światowe trendy eksploracji. „Przegląd Organizacji”, Vol. (9), pp. 17-20. Rusko R. (2011): Exploring the Concept of Coopetition: A Typology for the Strategic Moves of the Finnish Forest Industry. “Industrial Marketing Management”, pp. 311-320. Solitander M., Tidström A. (2010): Competitive Flows of Intellectual Capital in Value Creating Networks. “Journal of Intellectual Capital”, Vol. 11(1), pp. 23-38. Tidström A. (2008): Perspectives on Coopetition on Actor and Operational Levels. “Management Research”, Vol. 6(3), pp. 207-218. Tidström A. (2009): Causes of Conflict in Intercompetitor Cooperation. “Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing”, Vol. 7(24), pp. 506-518. Tranfield D., Denyer D., Smart P. (2003): Towards a Methodology for Developing Evidence-Informed Management Knowledge by Means of Systematic Review. “British Journal of Management”, Vol. 14(3), pp. 207-222 Tsai W. (2002): Social Structure of "Coopetition" within a Multiunit Organization: Coordination, Competition, and Intraorganizational Knowledge Sharing. “Organization Science”, Vol. 13(2), pp. 179-190. Vonortas N. (2000): Multimarket Contract and Inter-Firm Cooperation in R&D. “Journal of Evolutionary Economics”, Vol. 10, pp. 243-271. Walley K. (2007): Coopetition. An Introduction to the Subject and an Agenda for Research. “International Studies of Management & Organization”, Vol. 37(2), pp. 11-31. Wang Y., Krakover S. (2008): Destination Marketing: Competition, Cooperation or Coopetition? “International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management”, Vol. 20(2), pp. 126-141. Wolfe M. (1955): The Concept of Economic Sectors. “The Quarterly Journal of Economics”, Vol. 69(3), pp. 402-420. Yami S., Castaldo S., Dagnino G.B., Le Roy F. (2011): Coopetition – Winning Strategies for the 21st Century. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham. Yami S., Le Roy F. (2010): Stratégies de coopétition. Rivaliser et coopérer simultanément. De Boeck, Bruxelles. 150