DemiDec Fundamental Economics Resource
Transcription
DemiDec Fundamental Economics Resource
2012 2013 EDITION 18 YE AR S ING OU RB ECONOMICS ECONOMICS Post-Soviet Communist Recovery DO AUTHOR Niha Jain EDITOR Tania Asnes ® the World Scholar’s Cup® ALPACA-IN-CHIEF Daniel Berdichevsky EST , SO YO U CA N DO YO U RS Table of Contents Table of Contents............................................................................................................1 Preface .............................................................................................................................5 I. The Fundamentals .......................................................................................................7 The Basic Economic Problem—Scarcity ............................................................................................ 8 Production of Goods and Services ................................................................................................... 10 Increasing Costs............................................................................................................................... 11 Pareto Efficiency .............................................................................................................................. 12 The Factors of Production ............................................................................................................... 13 Benefit-Cost Analysis – Marginal Decision-Making......................................................................... 14 Marginal Utility and Waffles ........................................................................................................... 15 More on Marginal Utility and the Effect of Prices ........................................................................... 17 Individual and Social Goals ............................................................................................................. 18 Positive and Normative Economics ................................................................................................. 19 Economic Systems and their Characteristics .................................................................................... 19 The Basic Economic Questions ....................................................................................................... 20 What and how much to produce? ................................................................................................. 20 How to produce? .......................................................................................................................... 21 Who receives the benefits of production? ...................................................................................... 21 Responses to Positive and Negative Incentives ................................................................................. 22 Characteristics of a Mixed Market Economy ................................................................................... 23 Economic Freedom ...................................................................................................................... 23 Private Property ............................................................................................................................ 23 Economic Incentives..................................................................................................................... 23 Competitive Markets .................................................................................................................... 23 Limited Role of Government ........................................................................................................ 23 Voluntary Exchange ........................................................................................................................ 24 Specialization and Division of Labor ............................................................................................... 25 Introduction to Trade...................................................................................................................... 26 III. Microeconomics ......................................................................................................27 Markets ........................................................................................................................................... 27 Prices ............................................................................................................................................... 27 Demand .......................................................................................................................................... 28 Demand vs. Quantity Demanded .................................................................................................... 29 Changes in Consumer Income......................................................................................................... 30 Changes in the Number of Consumers ............................................................................................ 31 Changes in Consumer Expectations ................................................................................................. 31 Changes in Prices of Substitutes and Complements ......................................................................... 31 Changes in Consumer Tastes ........................................................................................................... 32 Seasonal Changes............................................................................................................................. 33 Supply ............................................................................................................................................. 33 Supply vs. Quantity Supplied .......................................................................................................... 34 Changes in the Costs of Factors of Production ................................................................................ 35 Technology...................................................................................................................................... 35 Expectation of a Price Change ......................................................................................................... 35 Number of Suppliers ....................................................................................................................... 36 Market Equilibrium......................................................................................................................... 36 Summarizing Equilibrium Changes ................................................................................................. 38 Price and Wage Controls ................................................................................................................. 38 Utility and Income .......................................................................................................................... 39 Elasticity .......................................................................................................................................... 42 Market Structures ............................................................................................................................ 44 Perfect Competition ........................................................................................................................ 44 Monopolistic Competition .............................................................................................................. 45 Oligopoly ........................................................................................................................................ 46 Monopoly........................................................................................................................................ 47 The Production Decision ................................................................................................................ 49 Price Discrimination........................................................................................................................ 50 The Institutions of a Market Economy ............................................................................................ 50 Financial Intermediaries .................................................................................................................. 51 Labor Unions .................................................................................................................................. 51 Property Rights................................................................................................................................ 52 Private Property Protection in the United States .............................................................................. 53 Types and Nature of Income ........................................................................................................... 54 Factor Markets and Derived Demand .............................................................................................. 55 The Labor Market ........................................................................................................................... 55 Wage Rates ...................................................................................................................................... 56 The Hiring Decision .................................................................................................................... 56 Human Capital Development and Labor Productivity .................................................................... 57 Returns on Investment in Education ............................................................................................... 57 Other Factors That Influence Income.............................................................................................. 58 Investment and Economic Growth .................................................................................................. 58 Entrepreneurs .................................................................................................................................. 60 IV. Macroeconomics .....................................................................................................61 Gross Domestic Product and National Income................................................................................ 61 Methods of GDP Measurement.................................................................................................... 62 The Expenditures Approach to GDP Measurement...................................................................... 63 The Income Approach to GDP Measurement .............................................................................. 63 The Output (Value-Added) Approach to GDP Measurement ...................................................... 65 Real GDP and Nominal GDP ...................................................................................................... 65 The Circular Flow of the Economy .............................................................................................. 66 Enter the Government .................................................................................................................. 67 Exports and Imports in the Circular Flow..................................................................................... 67 Economic Growth ........................................................................................................................... 67 The Business Cycle .......................................................................................................................... 68 Economic Indicators ........................................................................................................................ 69 Aggregate Demand .......................................................................................................................... 70 Consumption and the Marginal Propensity to Consume ................................................................. 73 The Multiplier Effect ....................................................................................................................... 74 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 3 “Ideal” vs. “Real” Multipliers ........................................................................................................... 75 Aggregate Supply and Economic Equilibrium.................................................................................. 75 The Labor Force .............................................................................................................................. 76 Categories of Unemployed Persons .................................................................................................. 77 Kinds of Unemployment ................................................................................................................. 78 Four Portraits of Unemployment..................................................................................................... 78 Money and Currency....................................................................................................................... 79 The Three Functions of Money ....................................................................................................... 80 Types of Money and the Money Supply .......................................................................................... 81 Inflation and Price Indices ............................................................................................................... 81 Interest Rates ................................................................................................................................... 86 Roles of the Government in a Market Economy .............................................................................. 87 Sales, Value Added, and Excise Taxes ........................................................................................... 88 Sales Taxes and Deadweight Loss ................................................................................................. 89 Lump Sum and Property Taxes .................................................................................................... 90 Income Taxes ............................................................................................................................... 90 Promoting Competition .................................................................................................................. 91 Positive and Negative Externalities of Public Policy ......................................................................... 92 Social Security ................................................................................................................................. 93 The American Welfare System ......................................................................................................... 93 Unemployment Compensation........................................................................................................ 94 Fiscal Policy ..................................................................................................................................... 95 Federal Taxes in the United States ................................................................................................... 96 Shortcomings of Fiscal Policy .......................................................................................................... 97 Budget Deficit and National Debt ................................................................................................... 97 The Federal Reserve System ............................................................................................................. 98 Monetary Policy Goals and the Employment Act of 1946 ............................................................... 99 Monetary Policy — History and Methods ....................................................................................... 99 Monetary Policy Tools .................................................................................................................. 102 Money, Supply and Demand ......................................................................................................... 103 Less Direct Controls over the Money Supply in the United States .............................................. 103 Key Terms .................................................................................................................................. 104 Advantages of Monetary Policy ...................................................................................................... 104 Disadvantages of Monetary Policy ................................................................................................. 105 Other Notable Economists ............................................................................................................ 106 Phillips Curve ............................................................................................................................. 106 Lorenz Curve .............................................................................................................................. 107 Laffer Curve ............................................................................................................................... 107 Say’s Law ....................................................................................................................................... 108 V. Trade and Globalization .........................................................................................109 Relative Price and Comparative Advantage .................................................................................... 109 Absolute Advantage ....................................................................................................................... 111 Exchange Rates .............................................................................................................................. 112 Economic Development Thresholds and Trends ........................................................................... 113 Why is this Country Different from All Other Countries? ............................................................. 113 Economic Development Organizations ......................................................................................... 114 International Monetary Fund (IMF) ............................................................................................. 115 The World Bank ........................................................................................................................... 116 The Gold Standard ........................................................................................................................ 116 Selected International Organizations ............................................................................................. 117 The Rise of GATT and the WTO ................................................................................................. 117 Trade Blocs and Free Trade Associations ....................................................................................... 119 Opposition to Globalization and Free Trade ................................................................................. 120 Trade Sanctions ............................................................................................................................. 121 Important Trade Blocs and Free Trade Agreements ....................................................................... 121 V. The Global Economic Crisis ...................................................................................123 The Economy Takes a Bubble Bath ............................................................................................... 123 The Great Recession ...................................................................................................................... 128 The Recession in America .............................................................................................................. 129 Opening the TARP Door ........................................................................................................... 129 Unpaid in America ..................................................................................................................... 130 Political Consequences ............................................................................................................... 131 The European Sovereign Debt Crisis ............................................................................................. 132 The Crisis Unfolds ..................................................................................................................... 132 All for On€................................................................................................................................. 138 Political Consequences ............................................................................................................... 138 The Crisis Elsewhere ..................................................................................................................... 138 Conclusion: Act V .......................................................................................................138 About the Authors .......................................................................................................138 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 5 Preface You don’t have to be reading this. You could be somewhere else instead. You could be with your best friend watching The Hobbit, or drinking tea. You could be taking surveys on the Internet for five dollars an hour. You could just be sleeping. What would you most like to be doing1? Whatever it is, that’s what economists call your opportunity cost. You can’t do it and study economics at the same time.2 It’s a trade-off: you have to choose. Economics is about making choices in a world where you can’t have it all. How do you decide what to do? Maybe you flip a coin. But most economists will tell you that, as a rational person, you’re choosing the activity that is the most valuable to you. They might describe your decision with fancy terms, like indifference curves and budget lines. Don’t worry about what all these things are, though. We’ll get to them much later. For now, think of economics as the study of common decisions—and the science of common sense. It’s about how you decide whether to eat a burger or a bowl of noodles. It’s about how a country decides whether to invest in education or in the military. It’s about whether the government should help you if you can’t find a job. Of course, it gets more complicated. It’s also about how the central bank of Turkey will try to slow down inflation—which is when the same amount of money buys you less today than it did a year ago. And it’s about whether American Airlines and British Airways will someday be allowed to merge. Economists are the advisors that help governments make these decisions. You don’t bring an economist with you when you go shopping, but many economists believe you carry an economist inside of you. They call this economist rational self-interest. You are motivated to do what is best for you. Even if you’re buying someone a gift, these economists say you are buying it because you benefit from giving the gift. Maybe someone gives you a gift in return, or says nice things about you to a potential date. Or maybe if you don’t buy it, the person expecting the gift will be upset with you. Is it worth spending $20 to prevent someone from being upset? Maybe. Is it worth spending $2,000? Maybe not.3 Looking at these numbers is an example of economic analysis. 1 The correct answer is not “snogging”. e.g. If you try reading this book while singing karaoke, your song will be strange and your friends will laugh at you. 3 Unless it is a very powerful someone. 2 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 6 In this resource, we will look at economic analysis in three different areas. First, we’ll consider the fundamentals of economics. We’ll think more about trade-offs and consider what consumption and production actually are. Then, we’ll move into microeconomics. Micro means small. Microeconomics is mostly about local decisions, the sort you make at the mall: what you buy, and whether a store stays in business. If the price of tea goes up, you may drink more coffee—and buy less tea.4 A fast food restaurant advertises that its new burger is the tastiest in town, even though it is almost the same as any other burger. When you finish the microeconomics chapter, you’ll understand when and why these things happen. Third, we’ll consider macroeconomics. Macro means large. We’ll look at ways to calculate how strong an entire economy is, and at different ways for the government to create jobs and encourage growth. We’ll consider what money really is and how banks work. We’ll also consider other economic models, such as communism, and dispel the notion that the United States is a completely free market society— just as the Soviet Union was never a completely communist society. These larger issues will lead us to international trade and development. Most economists agree that trade is basically good. China has prospered since opening to trade in the late 1970s; Americans use Samsung cell phones in New York while Malaysians eat at California Pizza Kitchens in Kuala Lumpur. There was even a Starbucks in China’s Forbidden City until 2007. Is everyone happier? We’ll investigate why and how trade works even between very different countries. In the last section, we’ll consider the global economic crisis—which brings together concepts from throughout this guide to help us understand a case study all of us are living through. Whether you are following the American presidential election or trying to decipher Russia’s economic outlook, you need to understand the context: a global economy facing its worst crisis since the Great Depression. No wonder many critics believe economics is a “dismal”—or sad—science. Don’t listen to them. Economics does deal with a lot of problems, from shortages of iPhones to this so-called Great Recession, but it also gives us the tools to start understanding and solving these problems. This guide will introduce you to those tools. After studying it, you may begin to recognize how lots of things you already know about the world and about how people behave connect. Newspaper headlines will make more sense to you5, and you’ll find yourself not just making decisions on the margin—but making them that way on purpose. Remember, you don’t have to be reading this. I hope you’ll decide to. Daniel Berdichevsky 4 5 I will never buy less tea. At least until there are no more newspapers. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 7 I. The Fundamentals If economics is a science, it is the science of common sense. Rocket science is hard because we aren’t always building rockets.6 Economics is easier because we all live in economies and make economic decisions. The formal study of economics is intended to make a model out of markets and monetary movements. A model is a representation of a system that allows us to make predictions about changes. For example, you might have a model for the behavior of your parents. If you get good grades, your parents take you out to celebrate. If you get bad grades, your parents may take away your videogames. This model helps you decide whether to get good grades. In economics, models help predict what will happen to the economy. If a terrorist releases smallpox in Moscow and millions of Russians die, what will happen to the demand for automobiles? An economic model suggests that, if there are fewer customers, there will be less demand. Models in economics get much more complicated than this, of course. The key is to remember that they only represent the real world. They try to include as many important factors and relationships as possible, but the real world is very complicated. Some people like to point to the butterfly effect when discussing complex systems that are hard to model. Imagine if a butterfly7 flapped its wings in Vladivostok. This seems like a small thing8, but weather is so complicated some scientists believe it could start a storm in Florida—9,000 miles away. In economics, you can never know every factor Debate it! that will affect people. Maybe on Wednesday, Resolved: That economic models mislead lawmakers. Iran will reveal it has nuclear weapons, causing stock markets to crash.9 If models were perfect, economists (and countries!) would all be rich. Supply and demand, the distribution of goods and services, the cost of energy production, the dangers—and even benefits!—of monopoly: these are just some of the areas in which economists create models to help countries and companies make economic decisions. Economics is a social science. Some of you have never studied a social science, but may be familiar with the so-called “hard” sciences, such as chemistry. Hard sciences use experiments and logic to answer questions about the natural world. Social sciences try to do the same with questions about societies— questions such as “does using Facebook lead to having fewer close friends?” Economics assumes people are rational actors—that they can weigh costs and benefits and decide what is best for them at any given time. If you’ve ever eaten too much dessert, or procrastinated on a paper, 6 My high school classmate Kevin did, filling them with dry ice and launching them at the gym. Or Mothra. 8 Unless it were Mothra. 9 Find a model to predict the behavior of North Korea and you’ll probably win a Nobel Prize. 7 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 8 you know this isn’t necessarily always true. But, for the sake of argument, economists pretend we always make the best possible decisions. A problem common to all social sciences is that they cannot isolate one factor at a time. It is hard to look at one variable—such as daily hours of Facebook usage—without getting it mixed up with everything else about people—such as their education level. It is also tough to conduct experiments on whole societies. Later we will discuss different theories for what caused the Great Depression. Though the results would be very interesting, no one will ever give an economist the power to repeat the Great Depression several times, adjusting one factor at a time, just to prove a theory. You shouldn’t worry too much: models may not be perfect, humans may not always act rationally, and social sciences may not be exact, but there is a lot we do know for sure about economics through history and observation. On Academic Decathlon multiple choice exams, therefore, questions will usually have clear “best” answers. In World Scholar’s Cup debates you may have to deal with trickier issues, but no one expects you to come up with detailed economic policies on a moment’s notice. One thing that will make economics easier to study is a principle called ceteris paribus. It is a Latin phrase for “all else held equal.” It means that, in considering economic problems, we only think about one thing changing at a time. If we want to know how many people are going to the movies, and someone tells us that the price of movie tickets has doubled, we assume that everything else is the same: the popcorn isn’t any better or any worse, the seats are no more and no less comfortable. If we didn’t adopt the principle of ceteris paribus, we would always have to worry about other factors mixing things up, and we could never answer anything for sure, even hypothetically. The Basic Economic Problem-----Scarcity There just isn’t enough of everything for everyone. That’s the basic economic problem: scarcity. If everyone could pluck whatever they wanted off trees, there would be no need for the formal study of economics.10 You could have all the iPhone 5s in the world for free11. Without scarcity, there would never be difficult decisions to be made by firms and people. But there is scarcity. One could even say there’s too much of it. Economists begin with a key assumption: that Debate it! humans have unlimited wants and that the world Resolved: That people do not really have unlimited wants. has only limited resources. Sure, there are times when we seem to have everything we want. And some people are easier to satisfy than others. Maybe you have a friend who just needs pizza and a pillow to survive quite contentedly. Still, the assumption about unlimited wants is generally accurate. Even a billionaire cannot be in Dubai and San Francisco on the same night for dinner with two different people.12 She has to make choices. Economics also assumes we try to do the best we can with what we have. And it assumes we try to do this rationally—making the best possible choice at any given time.13 10 Horticulture, however, would become rather fashionable. This assumes a very strange tree. 12 Unless she owns a military jet and can travel at Mach 5. 13 Studies are casting doubt on whether humans are truly rational. For example, we are often more afraid of losing $20 than enthusiastic about winning $20—and love can throw us totally out of whack. What does this imply for economics? 11 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 9 Of course, some resources are less limited than others. Some even seem to be available in sufficient amounts to everyone who wants them. Economists call these free goods. The most classic example of a free good is air. We breathe all the air we need and we don’t pay for it… do we? Let’s think some more about air. While we never go to “air restaurants” to order scoops of chocolate air, our societies do put a lot of effort into air. The government enforces pollution regulations and air quality standards. If factories release too much smoke, they are punished. As citizens, we pay taxes to fund the agencies that set standards and enforce regulations. Air is a free good, but clean air is not. Anything not a free good—just about everything—has a cost. When we study economics, we need to consider two main kinds of costs. The accounting cost of a good or service is the amount of money we spend on it. For example, the accounting cost of a lava lamp might be $59.99. Earlier we talked a bit about opportunity cost. We deal with opportunity cost whenever we make choices. Suppose that on Sunday, you can work at the Caribou Coffee in Youngstown for $50 or at the Nile Café for $35. You like the Nile, but you need the money, so you go work at Caribou. What does it cost you to make $50 at Caribou? It costs the $35 you could have made at the Nile. That $35 is your opportunity cost: the value of the best choice you didn’t make. Economists define opportunity cost as the value of the next-best alternative. Every choice has an opportunity cost. The opportunity cost of listening to Mozart might be the value of listening to Justin Bieber. The opportunity cost of attending college may be the lost salary from the job you could have had selling cars instead.14 Economists care about both kinds of costs. For most of their analysis, they measure economic cost, which includes both the accounting cost and the opportunity cost (plus other costs that we will talk about later, like damage to the environment and negative impacts on society). The economic cost of the lava lamp includes its accounting cost, the time and money you’ll spend driving to and from the store, the environmental impact of the synthetic materials used to create the lamp, and the social stigma you’ll experience when your friends see the thing in your room. 14 My cousin tried this, and reports the opportunity cost is not very high. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 10 Production of Goods and Services Suppose you live on a farm with five acres of land. Your family is in the business of producing juices. You can plant either orange trees or blueberry bushes on your land. If you use all the land to plant orange trees, you can produce 1,000 oranges per year. If you use all the land for blueberry bushes, you can produce 10,000 blueberries per year. The table displays some of your production possibilities. You can produce various blueberry and orange combinations. You might grow 800 oranges and 1,000 blueberries—or 9,000 blueberries and 100 oranges. The combinations are limited only by your total land. For example, you cannot grow 10,000 blueberries and 1,000 oranges. You don’t have enough land. Choosing the best mix is not easy. Some land is probably better for orange trees, some for blueberry bushes. If you grow only oranges, you will “waste” some land that is better for blueberries. If you produce mostly blueberries, you will make poor use of land perfect for oranges. We can represent all possible combinations of oranges and blueberries on a Production Possibilities Frontier (PPF). A PPF is one of the most fundamental diagrams in economic decision-making. It shows all possible combinations of two goods that a producer or country can output, given its resources and technology. The first graph highlights some of the combinations in which you might produce oranges and blueberries. If you choose to produce at point A, you’ll grow only blueberries—10,000 of them—and no oranges. At B, you’ll grow 5,000 blueberries and 400 oranges; at C, 1,000 blueberries and 800 oranges. Suppose we try to move away from the PPF, both inside and outside of it. The second graph highlights some production possibilities—X and Z—that do not fall on the frontier, as well as one, Y, that does. Imagine what would happen if you produced at X. You’d grow only 200 oranges and 800 blueberries. You might have your own reasons for producing at this point, but you’d probably frustrate an economist. Producing at X is considered inefficient because it doesn’t employ all available resources. To produce at Y, or any other point along the frontier, would be efficient. You’d be employing all available resources. PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES Oranges Blueberries 0 100 200 300 380 400 450 600 700 800 1,000 10,000 9,000 8,000 7,000 6,000 5,000 4,000 3,000 2,000 1,000 0 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 11 Suppose you decided to produce 5,300 blueberries and 2,300 oranges. This combination is represented by point Z. Because Z is outside the frontier, it is unattainable (except through trade—more on this later). You just don’t have the land or technology to produce that much fruit on your own. The PPF illustrates the trade-off we face when we decide how much to produce of each of two goods: to produce more of one, we must produce less of the other. Whenever we move along the frontier, from one point to another, we make a trade-off. In the third graph, a movement from point 1 to 2 indicates a tradeoff of 400 oranges for 4,000 more blueberries. The PPF can help us see a trade-off, but it won’t decide for us. We use goods and services to satisfy wants, but different people want different things in different amounts. Culture plays a role in this, too. Even two producers with exactly the same resources, and thus the same production possibilities, might produce different quantities to satisfy different wants. Increasing Costs Sometimes a PPF represents production possibilities for two very similar goods. In the graph to the right, a manufacturer compares production possibilities for black shoes and brown shoes. Since the cost and most of the materials involved in producing black and brown shoes are the same, the greatest number of shoes that can be manufactured in this example is always 80, whether the shoes are all one color or some are of each color. The materials and labor available will allow no more than 80 shoes to be made per day. At each point on the line, the total number produced is always 80. At point D, 60 black shoes and 20 brown shoes are made—again, 80 in all. Note that the PPF for black shoes and brown shoes is a straight line. When the PPF for any two goods is a straight line, we can infer that the opportunity cost of any change in production is the same anywhere along the line. For every black shoe made, one brown shoe is not made, and vice versa. It is a constant tradeoff. In the real world, most PPFs represent two very different goods. Often, PPF are used to represent a nation’s trade-off between military goods (usually referred to as “guns”) and civilian goods (usually referred to as “butter.”) Another important trade-off is between capital goods, like factories, and consumer goods, like iPads and tofu. In this guide, we use “milk or missiles” for our PPFs, but the actual items don’t matter very much. What matters is that the items, like milk and missiles, are very different. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 12 The curve to the right is the “standard” PPF. Unlike a straight line, it is “bowed” or curved outward from (concave to) the origin. At either end, the trade-offs are greater because opportunity costs are higher. If Decalon moves from A to B, it will produce 100 more missiles and give up only 50 billion quarts of milk. The more Decalon concentrates resources on missiles, the greater the trade-off will become. If Decalon moves from C to D, it gains another 100 missiles, but now it loses 220 billion quarts of milk. This reflects the law of increasing opportunity costs: the more you produce of a good, the greater the opportunity cost of producing it becomes. The law is not always true, but it usually holds for two main reasons. First, required resources become scarcer. We may need to dig deeper in mines to find metal for additional missiles. Second, as we require more inputs, we turn to those of less quality. Even if our mines had all the metal we needed, we would still need miners. Not everyone makes a good miner. Some people may even be claustrophobic. As we need more and more missiles, we are forced to assign resources to mining the metal—such as farmers and cows— that are much better at producing milk. Consider the situation at point D. Here, even if Decalon were to sacrifice all its remaining milk—320 billion quarts—it could only eke out another 50 missiles. PPFs can’t tell us which point is best. They can only tell Debate it! us the possibilities and their opportunity costs. Yes, many resources great for making milk will be used Resolved: That a country should favor capital goods over consumer goods. inefficiently if Decalon moves from D to E—but if Decalon is at war, those extra 50 missiles could make the difference between victory and defeat. If zombies are taking over the planet, Decalon might choose to produce only milk, to hold one last ice cream party prior to extermination.15 Pareto Efficiency We’ve been using the term efficiency without stopping to consider what it means. The term can be used in many ways—for example, I’m not the most efficient editor because I constantly check the Internet for political news updates and brew cups of tea—but, for the purposes of this guide, we will focus on one specific kind of efficiency: Pareto efficiency.16 If you can’t make anyone better off without making someone else worse off, you’ve achieved Pareto efficiency. Suppose an isolated town in Decalon, Acastan, produces 1,000 bottles of milk. As the mayor, you hire former Blockbuster employees to deliver milk all across town in a Pareto efficient way. There are exactly 100 people in Acastan. Soon, each one, including you, has received 9 bottles of milk. 15 Producers of The Walking Dead, take note. Named for the Italian economist Vilfredo Federico Damaso Pareto (1848-1923). It would have been inefficient to call it Vilfredo Frederio Damaso Pareto Efficiency. 16 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 13 “We’re done delivering milk,” the chief deliveryman reports. “Everyone has more than enough. We’re going to watch the Clippers game. Blake Griffin is a nasty dunker.” “But wait,” you tell him, “There are 100 bottles of milk still sitting in the warehouse.” The deliveryman sighs. He realizes what you’re about to say: this distribution of milk is not Pareto efficient. He could deliver more milk without taking milk away from anyone who already has it. “Okay,” he sighs, “I’m on it.” He takes the 100 bottles of milk, hands them to you, and says, “You now have 109 bottles of milk. There are none left in the warehouse. It’s Pareto efficient. Now I’m going to the game.” You want to stop him, but, as you lift a hand, you realize he’s outsmarted you: he can’t deliver any more milk to anyone else without taking some away from you. In any given situation, there are usually several possible Pareto efficient outcomes, and they are not necessarily all equally desirable—or equally fair. Sighing, you go home to make a lot of ice cream. The Factors of Production We’ve talked about PPFs without analyzing what kinds of resources are required to make goods and services. In one example, we talked about land for growing trees or bushes; in another, we talked about manufacturing cows and nuclear missiles. Trees would also require humans to collect fruit, just as the cows would need humans (or robots) to milk them. For nuclear missiles, we would need factories to produce the metal casing17; missiles don’t just grow on trees.18 Let’s classify these different resources. Economists call them the factors of production and divide them into four categories. Natural resources include land and anything found in nature. Land used in production—such as the space occupied by a factory—is a natural resource. In fact, most economists just refer to natural resources as land. This can be confusing, since rivers and trees are counted as land too, even though they are made of water and wood. In economic terms, producers pay rent to use natural resources. (This is not the same as the rent you pay for an apartment.) Capital refers to factors of production produced to help produce other goods and services. It includes factory equipment, laptops, nuts and bolts—anything made to make something else. Capital also includes intermediate goods, or natural resources processed into a new form. For example, coal in a mine is considered land. But once extracted, it is an intermediate good, or capital. In economic terms, producers pay interest for the use of capital. 17 18 We might also need the Russian mafia to provide us with enriched uranium. We now know two things that do not grow on trees: iPhone apps and nuclear missiles. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 14 Labor includes any physical and mental efforts by humans. In fact, it is also called “human resources.” When you work at a store, you are a human resource. In the language of economics, firms pay wages for the use of labor. The quality of human resources depends on a person’s human capital. Human capital includes education, experience, skills, and other training. Entrepreneurship refers to the ability to come up Debate it! with business plans, improve processes, or invent new products. Entrepreneurs figure out what to do with Resolved: That all young people should be taught how to be entrepreneurs. land, labor and capital. When a student drops out of college to start a social networking site, he is an entrepreneur. So is someone who opens an octopus burger stand outside an SAT school in Korea, betting the students will be hungry when they come out of class at 2 am. This word—betting—is crucial. Like gambling, being an entrepreneur means taking risk. A new business may fail. Most do. Entrepreneurs are rewarded with profit if they succeed, but they face a stiff opportunity cost; they could be working for someone else instead for a safe, steady salary. In some cultures, entrepreneurship is highly valued; in others, parents prefer that their children find stable, secure jobs as soon as possible.19 Benefit-Cost Analysis --- Marginal Decision-Making Economics is largely a study of decision-making. When a person weighs the benefits of something against its costs, he is conducting a benefit-cost analysis. A rational person or firm will decide to do something when its benefits outweigh its costs. If Anthony has studied economics, we can assume he will conduct a benefit-cost analysis before he decides whether to kill Ike. Consider Anthony, an ex-Decathlete pursuing his sworn enemy, Ike, through the badlands of Texas. Anthony plans to kill Ike. When Anthony catches up to Ike in front of a Krispy Kreme, several police officers are lingering out front. Anthony pauses to weigh the costs and benefits of killing Ike on the spot. The benefit is obvious: his sworn enemy will be dead. The costs are uncertain, but potentially significant. Anthony knows that, in Texas, murder carries the death penalty. The police will witness his crime; he will end up imprisoned or executed.20 If Anthony decides that Ike being dead is more valuable than the years of his life he will waste behind bars, he will kill Ike. However, if he decides that a dead Ike is no good to him if he loses his freedom, he will probably let Ike go—this time. We cannot make the decision for Anthony, because every person will measure the benefits and costs of that decision differently. Some of us might prefer freedom, others the death of a nemesis. What we do know is that if Anthony is rational, he will conduct a benefit-cost analysis before he makes his decision—even if he doesn’t call it that. Not all costs are the same. Some may be sunk costs: costs that cannot be avoided. Sometimes, this is because the sunk costs have already been paid; other times, they have been committed to. The sunk costs in a typical apartment lease represent both types. Suppose you are six months into a yearlong lease. You have already paid six months of rent—and, if you want to move somewhere else, you are still stuck paying the next six months (or some agreed-upon penalty). 19 20 These parents are usually not thrilled when their children choose to study English or Philosophy. Unless he hires a very good defense attorney. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 15 Sunk costs should never affect a rational decision—but they often do. People are often reluctant to give up something they have already paid for, even if doing so might save them money or improve their lives in the long run. Psychology plays a large role in real world economics. For Anthony, the distance he ran before catching Ike are a sunk cost. As he hyperventilates, he might think, “I’ve already run two miles to catch Ike. That counts for something! I should kill him!” Maybe so—but, to an economist, those two miles don’t count for anything. He can never get back the time and energy he spent running. Perhaps the future benefit of killing Ike would outweigh the past cost of running two miles. But Anthony should kill Ike only if the future benefits of having him dead outweigh the future costs of killing him. Of course, real economic decisions rarely involve questions of murder. Dramatic economic decisions might include whether to double the prices of all tickets to Miami Heat games—but most economic decisions are even more mundane. From month to month, a firm might simply decide whether to increase or decrease production of a product—say, donuts. It would weigh the benefits of producing one more donut against the costs of producing it. That “one more donut” is said to be at the margin. It would not consider the past cost of leasing a donut factory or of training the donut makers. Marginal decision-making is the act of weighing the benefits of an incremental change against its costs. The marginal benefit of an increase in production is the added revenue from the sale of one more unit. The marginal cost is the cost of producing it, including labor and materials. Suppose Sue’s Spaghetti is a small company that grows pasta on Noodlebushes®. Sue is deciding how many to plant. She must first evaluate her marginal benefits and costs. For Sue, the marginal benefit of another Noodlebush is the money she will receive from the sale of the noodles it produces. The marginal cost is the cost of producing another Noodlebush, including labor, time, land, and materials. Below is a table of the marginal costs versus marginal benefits as production increases. How many Noodlebushes should Sue plant to Noodlebush # Marginal Cost Marginal Benefit maximize her benefits? Consider one marginal 1 2 7 decision at a time. Each Noodlebush yields one 2 3 7 box of spaghetti, and the selling price of a box is 3 5 7 4 8 7 $7. Thus, the marginal benefit from each 5 12 7 Noodlebush is $7. (Marginal benefit is not always 6 17 7 this constant.) The cost of producing the first box of spaghetti is $2, so Sue will plant the first bush: she will earn more than $2 in revenue. She will also plant the second bush, because the $3 cost is still outweighed by the $7 benefit. The same goes for the third bush. But for the fourth, the marginal cost is greater than the benefit—$8 of cost versus $7 of benefit. Using marginal decision-making, Sue stops at three bushes. Marginal Utility and Waffles If we have unlimited wants, how is it that we ever feel we have enough of something? Blame the law of diminishing marginal utility (also known as diminishing returns): as we obtain more of a product or service, we tend to derive less value from each additional unit of it. Debate it! Resolved: That students should allocate their study time on the margin. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 16 Before we begin, you need to know a few terms. Utility is the satisfaction a person derives from consuming something. Marginal utility (MU) is the satisfaction derived from one more of something. Total utility is the sum of all the satisfaction a person derives from however many units of something he has consumed. Economists express utility in imaginary units they call utils. If a meat-loving person obtains 10 utils from a cheeseburger or 1 util from a slice of tofu, we can quantify how much more satisfaction he will derive from the cheeseburger. Utils don’t exist, but they make it easier to discuss utility. (Keep in mind that utils are not the same as units of happiness—economists aren’t able to measure happiness directly.21) Consider the case of a man I knew in high school, Steve. Steve ran track, and has a typical runner’s metabolism. He eats twice as much as the rest of us, but stays rail-thin. He is also always hungry. Steve claims to have been full only once in his life—when, on a whim, he decided just to eat as much as he could. He sat down at his table with a toaster, syrup, and several boxes of frozen waffles.22 Steve was very hungry, so the first few waffles tasted great. He wolfed them down as quickly as they popped out of the toaster. Steve’s marginal utility for each waffle was very high. Around number 12, the waffles began tasting like cardboard. Since Steve still didn’t feel full, he continued eating. The marginal utility Steve derived from each waffle was falling, but still positive. Though Steve wasn’t enjoying the waffles, they were still reducing his hunger, so they offered some utility. By number 25, Steve hated waffles. His jaws were sore from chewing. But he was not full yet, so he kept eating. Steve is very stubborn and had set out to do something. That was enough to keep his marginal utility positive and to keep him going. When it was over, Steve had eaten 36 waffles.23 At that point, he finally felt full, and the marginal utility of eating another waffle would have been negative. It would have caused him more trouble than it was 21 Only Disneyland has a handle on that science. I prefer mine with peanut butter, cream cheese and fresh blueberries. 23 Steve should probably go into hot dog eating contests. 22 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 17 worth—stomach sickness, a migraine, death. When I asked him if he ever wanted to try it again, he said no, once was enough. Even the feeling of being full suffers from diminishing returns. Even when Steve began to find the waffles less satisfying, he continued eating because he continued to derive some utility from them. Even when marginal utility is diminishing, total utility continues to increase as long as marginal utility remains positive. The graph below represents Steve’s total utility. Note how it continued to increase all the way to waffle 36—when marginal utility turned negative. More on Marginal Utility and the Effect of Prices Imagine that you crawl out of the desert near Baghdad and find an abandoned pawnshop. Inside it are bottles of water and diamond rings. All are free. What would you do, assuming your MU for each product is as displayed? Your first thought is of water.25 You’re half-dead of thirst. Weighing the MU of the first water bottle against that of the first ring, you decide to start with water. It doesn’t matter whether it’s from Fiji or from Aquafina’s sewage purification plant. Next, you weigh the MU of a second bottle (2,000 utils) against the MU of a first ring (1,500 utils). Thirst still wins out, so you grab another bottle. Quantity MU of a Bottle of Water MU of a Diamond Ring 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 1,000,000 2,000 50 30 10 20 10 5 1,500 1,200 1000 900 850 800 750 700 Apple TV and Marginal Utility I recently gave my mom-----the DemiMom!-----an Apple TV. ‘‘I want to watch TV shows while I exercise,’’ she said. On installing it I showed her she had two options. One was to rent shows for 99 cents each from iTunes. The other was to pay $7.99 per month for unlimited shows from Netflix. With the first option, she was carefully deciding what she might rent. When I explained the second option, she said, ‘‘Now I can try an episode of something I’m not sure about.’’ Consider this reasoning in terms of marginal utility and marginal cost. With iTunes rentals, each show had a marginal cost of 99 cents; my mom wanted to be sure a show had at least that much marginal utility before renting it. With the Netflix model, the marginal cost on any given show was effectively 024-----so she could risk unknown shows more easily. By now you’re feeling better—in fact, you’re wondering where to find a toilet. When the third round of consumption comes around, a ring is worth 1,500 utils to you and a bottle of water only 50. You grab your first ring. You can see how this is going. It’s doubtful you’ll take any more water for a long, long while. Let’s add prices. You see, the pawnshop isn’t abandoned. In fact, a Halliburton employee is running it. He insists you buy the water at $20 per bottle. He’s also charging $750 for each diamond ring. You have enough money to buy whatever you want, but you don’t want to waste it. What to do? The answer lies in the ratio of marginal utility to price: MU/P. MU/P is the amount of utility something will bring you per dollar spent. In other words, MU/P tells you what will give you the “best bang for the buck.” In theory, you will spend each dollar where it will do you the most good. 24 Of course, as an economics student, you would want to remind her about opportunity cost: an hour spent watching Sarah Palin’s Alaska is an hour that could have been spent watching Pushing Daisies—or cleaning lint out of your socks. 25 Unless you’re about to propose to a desert lizard and haven’t bought a ring yet. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 18 Quantity MU for Water MU/P for Water MU for Ring MU/P for Ring 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 1,000,000 2,000 50 30 25 15 10 5 50,000 100 2.5 1.5 1.25 .75 .5 .25 1,500 1,200 1000 900 850 800 700 600 2 1.6 1.3 1.2 1.13 1.07 .93 .8 You’ll buy goods in the order of their marginal utility per dollar, starting with the highest (50,000 for the first water bottle). From there, you’ll get two more bottles with ratios of 100 and 2.5 respectively, followed by two rings with ratios of 2 and 1.6. Next, you’ll want another bottle (your fourth) at 1.5, a ring (your third) at 1.3, another bottle (number five) at f 1.25 and three more rings at ratios of 1.2, 1.13, and 1.07, respectively. Eventually, your dollars just won’t be working very hard for you, and you’ll choose to keep the money rather than buy either a ring or water. Individual and Social Goals When people make decisions out of rational Discuss it! self-interest, they optimize by maximizing their Are you familiar with examples of groupthink in your own individual utility. But what happens when a group of people gets together and tries to make experience and in your own country? Discuss these examples with your teammates and online with teams at other schools. a decision? Most rational people do what is best for them individually, so putting them together in a group with a common goal can result in interesting outcomes (as any Decathlon or World Scholar’s Cup team will prove). When the group’s output can only be measured collectively, each member knows no one will notice if he or she contributes a little bit less. This behavior is called shirking or social loafing26 and is, like all economic phenomena, the result of rational self-interest. Shirking reduces the productivity of the group and makes a manager necessary to ensure all individuals are putting in maximum effort. Groups aren’t always less productive than individuals; having different perspectives is often crucial to economic decision-making. But even diverse groups with good intentions can be counterproductive. Social psychologist Irving Janis researched various government fiascos and coined the term groupthink, a condition in which everyone agreeing to a bad decision is blinded by its popularity. In the United States, many critics have argued Watch it on YouTube that the invasion of Iraq in 2003 was in part the result of groupthink. Intelligence services such In 1961, President Kennedy authorized what turned into one of the greatest disasters of his presidency-----the invasion of Cuba as the CIA affirmed the president’s statements by a CIA-trained group of Cuban exiles. The operation failed about the looming threat of Iraqi weapons of spectacularly. The lead-up to the Bay of Pigs disaster is often mass destruction; military officers cited as a textbook example of groupthink. Learn more at underestimated the difficulty of bringing peace http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=rKlnM_n1s1E to Iraq after an invasion. The militant atmosphere in Washington arguably kept anyone from voicing—or even contemplating—strong 26 Social loafing can also be explained by a game of tug-of-war. If there are many people tugging the rope at the same time, then each person would give less effort, thinking that the rest of the group would pick up the slack. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 19 opposition to the president’s certainty about the merits of an invasion. Positive and Normative Economics There are two types of analysis in economics: positive and normative. A positive economic statement is a statement that can be proven or disproven with facts. As with positive statements in philosophy, a positive economic statement is falsifiable. That is, it could potentially be shown to be wrong. A positive statement does not need to be correct. It can even be about the future. A statement such as “The world will end in 2012” is positive because we will know if it is right or wrong by 2013. NORMATIVE ECONOMICS opinionated, subjective economics POSITIVE ECONOMICS factual economics, unbiased statements of theory Like scientific theories, economic theories are stated positively. Theories are stated without biased language, usually in the form of “If X, then Y.” Here’s a theory: if you read this guide, your score will increase. This could be proven wrong if you read this guide and your score decreases. A normative economic statement is a judgment, a statement of opinion. It may interpret facts, but it can be neither proved nor disproved with facts. A normative statement might express something that “ought to” or “should” be an economic goal, or it might express how a goal “ought” to be pursued. “The World Bank should focus on rebuilding Haiti in 2011” is a normative statement. Let us review. To make a positive economics statement, you might say, “If we raise the excise tax on tobacco, then people will buy fewer cigarettes.” You could also say, “They raised the excise tax on tobacco last week.” To make a normative statement, you might say this: “We should raise the excise tax on tobacco in order to punish smokers for their stupidity.” Economic Systems and their Characteristics There are different kinds of economic systems. We can tell them apart by how resources are owned and by how economic decisions are made. A traditional economy relies on what has been done in the past to determine what should be done today. Traditional economies do not have much contact with the rest of the global economy. Some examples can be found in parts of Bhutan, Brazil and Burkina Faso. Even in developed countries, remote areas often maintain aspects of traditional economies. Watch it on YouTube North Korea is one of the last remaining closed societies on Earth. For a glimpse of this fascinating, unpredictable country-----in which a dead man continues to hold supreme power-----check out one of several documentaries on YouTube, filmed with varying degrees of permission from the North Korean government. Here’s one to get you started: http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=FJ6E3cShcVU Discuss It Some people suggest the economy should be overseen by experts without political ideologies. Do such experts exist? In a pure market economy, all economic resources are owned by private parties. Those individuals (and entities such as corporations) make all economic decisions, and there is no government intervention. Such economies do not actually exist, though some come close, with only minimal government intervention for things like national defense. In a planned economy, like North Korea’s, all land is publicly owned. A single central authority, such as Gosplan in the former Soviet Union, makes all economic decisions. When this authority has absolute ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 20 power, the system can also be described as a command economy. Command and planned economies are often designed around master plans, which dictate how everything will be produced and distributed. In reality, there are no pure economies of any kind. All real-world economies are mixtures of different systems. The United States has a mixed market economy. It promotes private enterprise, but the government intervenes to help achieve certain goals (such as lowering unemployment27). The United States also has traditions that affect economic activity. For instance, Thanksgiving affects the total production and consumption of turkeys, and very few restaurants open on Christmas. The Basic Economic Questions All economic systems exist to fight scarcity. To do so, each must answer basic economic questions: What and how much to produce? Should we produce more capital goods or more consumer goods? Should we produce more hybrid cars or more minivans? How many more of one than the other? In a market economy, the interaction between buyers and sellers in “the market” answers the question of what to produce. Suppliers produce and sell what consumers want to buy, and vice versa. Of course, individuals who own the means of production can always go against the market, but this would be to their detriment. No one wants to sell something no one wants to buy. Running (a long way between) the tables When I ate at a restaurant in former Soviet Georgia in 2000, I saw plenty of evidence of the country’s communist past. A handful of small tables dotted a large room, there were a dozen waiters, and there was no menu. Why would something like this happen? Since until recently no one had paid rent based on square footage, there was no incentive to use space efficiently. The government had supplied the wages, so it was no big deal to have too many waiters. And since the menu depended on what food happened to be available, there was no sense in printing one. Debate it! Resolved: That the postal service should be allowed to go In a command (or planned) society, the bankrupt. government or a central group decides what to produce. Long-term plans are often implemented—such as the famous Five Year Plans of China and the Soviet Union. Such plans may not work perfectly, since it is hard to dictate things like the weather or worker productivity—but, even when they fall short, they steer the economy one way or the other. The United States relies mostly on the market to answer this question. The government accounts for over a quarter of GDP, and many government programs play important roles in everyday life. The government also cajoles people and firms to take certain actions with tax incentives. For example, the “clash for clunkers” program gave people tax credits if they exchanged gas-guzzling older cars for more efficient newer models. The tax deduction on mortgage interest encourages home ownership. The government also imposes regulations on private industry, dictating pollution limits, safety standards, and consumer rights. If the government chose to, it could even regulate caffeine as a drug. 27 Or, if you’re in San Francisco, forbidding Happy Meals. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 21 How to produce? This is a question of how we use our scarce resources to produce the goods and services we want. Should we subsidize farmers who farm organically? Should the United States outsource all customer support services to call centers in India—or, as Indian wage rates rise, to Indonesia? In a pure market economy, suppliers decide how to produce goods or services. To a producer, the best method of production is usually the method that maximizes profit. In a command (or planned) economy, the government or a central authority decides how to produce. This has resulted in some disasters, such as Mao’s decision to have the production of steel undertaken by rural villages instead of large, urban factories. The resulting steel was useless; desperate farmers even melted their tools to meet his demands, contributing to a famine that killed millions. In a mixed market system, this question is answered by both the market and the government. Firms generally try to produce in the ways that maximize profit. The government sometimes subsidizes less efficient industries to ensure they can compete or deliver needed services. For example, the United States government runs the postal service, because, if it were a private company, it would cut back on or raise prices on mail delivery to rural communities.28 The government also imposes regulations. For example, in most developed countries, firms can’t set up sweatshops to produce goods (though they can cheerfully import goods from sweatshops abroad). Who receives the benefits of production? While the first two questions were mainly questions of efficiency, the third is mainly a question of equity. Is it fair that only those who can afford food and shelter should survive? Should age be a factor in determining who should have jobs and resources? What about race or gender? Is the current distribution of wealth and resources desirable? Should Paris Hilton enjoy a cut in her inheritance tax or should middle-class households be given a cut in their income tax? In theory, a major advantage of a communist command economy is that it ensures everyone shares in the benefits of production. No one will starve, and everyone will have a place to live. That kind of idyllic promise is what drew people to such economies in the first place. But, of course, the central authority may be corrupt29 or incompetent—or it may value equity at the expense of opportunity. In the United States, a mixed market economy, this question is again answered by both the market and the government. Public education is offered to everyone, and there are many government programs that transfer money to needy individuals—welfare, housing projects, health insurance for veterans, subsidized student loans, and so forth. All Americans benefit from highways, trash collection, and water projects. Still, they can’t all drive fancy cars or eat sushi every night; market forces decide who will receive those less fundamental benefits. We can differentiate economic systems by comparing who answers the basic economic questions: 28 Think about how much more expensive it must be to deliver a letter to rural Alaska—or to American Samoa—than to Boston. Yet each costs the same stamp. That is not an efficient market. 29 Sure, says the communist ruler, everyone is given a place to live. Mine just happens to be nicer than everyone else’s. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 22 Market Planned/Command Mixed What and How Much to Produce? the market a central authority the market and the government How to Produce? individuals and firms a central authority individuals, firms, and the government For Whom to Produce? the market a central authority the market and the government Responses to Positive and Negative Incentives Economics assumes people respond in predictable ways to incentives. A self-interested individual or firm will consider all relevant benefits and costs when making decisions—trying to maximize benefits and minimize costs. Since we know (in economics) that people make these calculations, consciously or subconsciously, we can come up with incentives to motivate people to make the decisions we like. A positive incentive is a reward for behavior meant to encourage that behavior. An airline will give out frequent flyer miles to people for flying that airline. The goal is to give people a reason to keep flying that airline, by promising that the points will lead to rewards and privileges—such as upgrades. A negative incentive is a punishment (cost) for behavior deemed undesirable by whoever is dishing out the punishment. For example, police departments will issue fines to discourage speeding, and the government will audit suspicious tax returns to discourage cheating. An example: if Jonathan is a typical high school student and you tell him you will give him $50 to bring you a yogurt, it is easy to predict he will do it. Similarly, if you hold a gun up to Jonathan’s head and tell him you will shoot him unless he brings you a Coca Cola, again, he will probably do it30. To Jonathan, the $50 are a positive incentive for bringing you the yogurt, and being shot is a negative incentive for not bringing it. That you might be executed for killing him is probably irrelevant to his decision-making; he wants to live more than he wants you to die. Jonathan’s responses are predictable because he responds in the way that maximizes his utility, whether it is maximizing his gain or minimizing his loss. The money offers positive utility, so he brings you yogurt to increase his total utility. A bullet through his skull promises negative utility (think of the hospital bills). To avoid decreasing total utility, he brings you the Coke. Of course, $50 might not be enough of a positive incentive to someone else. Jonathan’s classmate Jacqueline might see taking your orders as such an insult that the negative utility of doing what you want outweighs a $50 gain. We never know exactly how a person will respond to an incentive; people’s values vary too much. But, if we know a person sees something as a positive incentive, we can predict he will take it. If we know a different person sees the same thing as a negative incentive, we can predict she will avoid it. They make different choices, but both are maximizing their utility. Economists assume people behave according to rational self-interest. An economist does not see people as good or evil, just as rational, well-informed and self-motivated. Recent research suggests people may not be that rational after all.31 Still, in aggregate, the assumption that they are rational and motivated by self-interest will help us understand the economy. 30 31 Unless he’s actually Jack Bauer, in which case he’ll find a way to kill you with the Coca Cola. I’m surprised this took a while to figure out. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 23 Don’t mix up self-interest with money. Yes, people are (almost always) interested in money. But they’re also interested in other things, such as family, respect and leisure. People can be motivated by both monetary and non-monetary incentives. Suppose you’re a manager at a multinational Debate it! corporation hoping to make its low-wage workers more efficient and enthusiastic. You Resolved: That people are motivated mainly by self-interest. could raise their wages. But suppose you wanted to use non-monetary incentives. Perhaps you could call employees “associates” or “team members” and award the most effective of them special prizes each month. You might also remind them frequently of how important they are to you and of what a difference they are making in the lives of your clients. Such non-monetary incentives can motivate employees even in the absence of larger paychecks. Characteristics of a Mixed Market Economy Economic Freedom A market economy requires freedom of choice for consumers and producers, so they can decide which goods and services to consume and produce, and so they can independently determine what prices they are willing to spend and charge for them. Private Property Businesses, land, and homes are owned by individuals or by shareholders, not by the government. Decisions are made by independent women and men, looking out for their own interests. Economic Incentives The most common incentive is “profit motive.” Most people desire more things. Those who work harder tend to earn more and can purchase more of the goods and services they desire, reaching a higher standard of living. People can thus “move up” in society. A market economy cannot sustain a rigid class system because it would prevent people who work hard from becoming wealthier. Competitive Markets There is economic “rivalry” between producers and between consumers. Businesses compete for buyers. Competition leads to better, cheaper goods for consumers. Consumers compete to obtain goods and services from sellers. Some consumers are willing to pay more to ensure they will get what they want. In a competitive market, inefficient firms and producers are forced out of business if they don’t continually improve their offerings or their prices. Limited Role of Government Most market economists believe efficiency will decline if the government interferes too much with natural market forces—say, by restricting trade—leading to higher prices and less output. However, even the most passionate market economists agree the government has some indispensable roles. For example, it enforces laws that protect private property, and has the authority to pursue and punish criminals and to deploy armed forces to protect the country. A more controversial government role is to “level the playing field” by regulating or even breaking up monopolies and trusts. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 24 Voluntary Exchange When you make an exchange, you trade one thing for another. You can exchange something for money, or for another resource, good, or service. In this guide, we’re mostly concerned with voluntary exchanges—but consider what an involuntary exchange might be. If the government seizes your house to build a bypass, paying you something for your trouble, you have enjoyed an involuntary exchange.32 Voluntary exchanges are easy to imagine; we engage in them all the time. Both parties in a voluntary exchange expect to gain. When you buy a house, you expect to gain shelter, property and social status. The person selling it expects to gain cash. When two baseball teams trade players, both expect benefits; no one ever makes a trade to lose. One form of voluntary exchange is barter, which happens Even the most primitive economies have when we exchange resources, goods, or services for other found ways to avoid barter. resources, goods or services. No money is involved. Normally, we have no trouble making the occasional exchange without money, but we would have a terrible time trying to run a whole economy that way. Barter only works if there is a double coincidence of wants. It isn’t enough for you to have something I want. Unless you also want what I have, we cannot barter. Suppose you live in a barter economy and you fish for a living. You’re sick of sleeping on the beach33, so you decide to build a house. You need a hammer, some nails and a pile of wood. You go to see the hammer-maker and offer her 10 fish for a hammer. She replies that she’s allergic to fish but would love to trade a hammer for 15 eggs. Okay—you go to the chicken-grower and ask him if he’ll trade 10 fish for 15 eggs. He says that fish make him gag but he loves spaghetti. It just so happens that his neighbor grows spaghetti and loves fish. Progress! You walk next door and offer the neighbor 10 fish in exchange for the fruit of one Noodlebush, take the spaghetti to the chicken-grower and get the eggs, and bring the eggs to the hammer-maker and get your hammer. Now you need to find some nails and wood. See the problem? Bartering demands tremendous time and effort. Imagine an economy full of people trying to barter, and you can understand why most societies have found ways to avoid it. Money is the most straightforward solution: it eliminates barter by functioning as a medium of exchange. You could have sold your fish for money. Then you could have approached the hammer-maker and offered her money for a hammer. You could then have bought all the other items you needed to build your house. With money, there would have been no need to deal with the Noodlebushes, or to carry around dead fish. A market would have helped your situation even more. A market is a mechanism that brings buyers and sellers together to make exchanges. Some markets are real places, such as grocery stores, swap meets, and used car lots, where buyers and sellers physically come together. Some markets are online, like eBay and Amazon. In the example above, you could have gone to a fish market and waited for someone to come buy your fish—then walked over to the hardware market for supplies. 32 33 It’s not the end of the world, but it’s not ideal, either. Or, it could in fact be the end of the world. It gets old, especially when the tide rises and takes away your backpack. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 25 Specialization and Division of Labor If you have ever read Laura Ingalls Wilder’s semi-autobiographical novel Little House on the Prairie, you may have been impressed by her family’s self-sufficiency. Her mom ground wheat into flour, baked, raised chickens and cows, cooked, did laundry, pumped water, sewed clothes, and raised children. She made sugar from tree sap and soap from pig fat. Her father chopped down trees, grew crops, and built houses and wagons. He trained horses and slaughtered pigs. He even shot raccoons to make fur hats. Laura’s parents bought a few things, but did nearly everything for themselves. Imagine we sent this guide back in time. Laura’s mom finds it in the prairie and opens it to this section. After reading it, she realizes she’s had it all wrong. She runs from farm to farm and rallies farmwives for “something really important.” Soon, five are gathered in her living room. She asks each about her chores and notes how much they produce. Laura’s mom realizes each of the wives is particularly skilled at one thing. On a chart, she circles each woman’s productive specialty. Name Anna-Lee Barbara-Jean Laura’s Mom Mae-Belle Mae-Jean Sarah Group Total Pounds of Flour Ground Children Raised 3 2 2 4 3 5 1 2 1 1 2 10 6 22 Productive Output for One Month Loaves of Bread Chickens Raised Baked 16 6 15 8 14 7 13 5 4 20 8 6 86 36 Cows Raised 1 1 1 Loads of Laundry Done 12 15 28 16 20 26 117 3 2 1 9 Clearly, Anna-Lee is the best flour-maker. Mae-Jean can produce the most loaves of bread. Mae-Belle raises more cows than any of the others, even though she has three children. After a short pep talk from Laura’s mom, the women agree: they are overworked and have not time for fun. There has got to be a better way. Laura’s mom proposes theyen pool their efforts. Each can specialize in the thing she does best. Everyone can do her specialty for the whole group, and then no one will have to handle all those chores alone. It’s an easy sell. The women agree to become interdependent. Fast-forward a year. The women have finally had the chance to enjoy some time off. Laura’s mom calls a meeting to discuss group productivity. She estimates their new productive capacity: Anna-Lee Barbara-Jean Laura’s Mom Mae-Belle Mae-Jean Sarah Group Total Previous Total Increased Productivity Pounds of Flour Ground 30 0 0 0 0 0 30 10 20 Children Raised 0 0 0 0 0 22 22 22 - Productive Output for One Month Loaves of Bread Chickens Raised Baked 0 0 0 36 0 0 0 0 200 0 0 0 200 36 86 36 114 - Cows Raised 0 0 0 9 0 0 9 9 - Loads of Laundry Done 0 0 150 0 0 0 150 117 33 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 26 It turns out the cooperative produces 20 more pounds of flour, 114 more loaves of bread, and 33 more loads of laundry than the women on their own. And the women now have leisure time.34 Like the women in the co-op, most people today are specialists. Sure, some fix cars or bake for fun, but most specialize in the fields where they can be most productive, and use their income to buy other goods and services. Like the women in the co-op, they grow interdependent. We count on other people to specialize in other things, and to pay us for our specialties. Consider an example from the professional world. If, in college, you like critical thinking and you have writing skills, you could go on to specialize in law. On the other hand, if you prefer biology, you might become a doctor. This is far more practical than for everyone to try to become both lawyers and doctors. If we did that, people wouldn’t get out of school until they were 40, and many of them would be very mixed up. As a lawyer, if you become sick, you will be dependent on a doctor to help you; if, as a doctor, you are sued, you will need to sign up a lawyer to represent you. In either profession, you will be dependent on other specialists. The result is overall interdependence. The assembly line is another example from the real world. It reflects division of labor: splitting production into separate tasks. The advantage is that workers on the line only have to learn one small part of the production process. They become very specialized. The disadvantage is they are so interdependent that if one worker fails to complete his job, the whole process could fail. Workers can also grow bored, or depressed, and can often be replaced with machines. Introduction to Trade A country, too, can improve the quality of life for its people by trading with other countries. Any country (even North Korea) can export goods—sell them to other countries—or import goods—buy them from other countries. When the United States sends Fords to Mexico, it is exporting. If you buy French cheese in a Kuala Lumpur supermarket, you have purchased an import.35 Unless a country happens to import exactly as much as it exports, it will either import more than it exports or export more than it imports. The balance of trade is the ratio of a country’s imports to its exports. It is simply a measure of whether a country is importing more or exporting more and by how much. If we import more than we export, we are running a trade deficit. If we export more than we import, we are running a trade surplus. We can run a trade deficit with one country—like China—and a surplus with another—like Samoa—at the same time. Sometimes countries want to import less of something from abroad. To achieve this they impose trade barriers, or restrictions on trade. Trade barriers are a form of protectionism. They protect domestic markets from global competition, but can also be used to pressure or punish a country. One trade barrier is a tariff, a tax on an import. Another is a quota, a limit on how much of a good that may be exported or imported. Typically, quotas are imposed on imports. The most restrictive trade barrier is an embargo, which prohibits any exchange. Embargos can be imposed on a single good, an industry, a country or any combination of these (e.g. all cigars from Cuba). We will come back to this topic, and to larger issues in trade and development. First, we will turn to the markets within a given country. 34 35 The space-time continuum has probably been destroyed, but who’s counting? This is true even if the supermarket in Kuala Lumpur is owned by the French, as it very well might be. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 27 III. Microeconomics Traditionally, the study of economics is divided into two broad areas: microeconomics and macroeconomics. In microeconomics, we study the economic decision-making of individuals and firms and the consequences of those decisions. In microeconomics, we isolate the behavior of individual markets and we try to explain how they function and what will cause their behavior to change. When you decide how much salmon to buy at Carrefour and when Toyota decides how many cars to manufacture in Osaka, these decisions are being made at a microeconomic level. In macroeconomics, we look at the overall economy and try to understand how all the parts interact. We might try to measure the size of the economy or we might try to assess its health. We might also predict, rightly or wrongly, how a policy change could affect the economy. In this resource, we first explore microeconomics, then macroeconomics. While not everything you’ll learn in the study of microeconomics will apply directly to macroeconomics, most of what you’ll learn in “micro” will be foundational to your understanding of “macro.” Markets Earlier, we defined a market as any mechanism that brings buyers and sellers together to exchange goods, services, and/or money. A swap meet is a classic example, but a store, a restaurant, a garage sale, a hotel, eBay, Amazon.com and the New York Stock Exchange are all markets. In economics jargon, buyers demand goods and services. Sellers supply them. When buyers and sellers interact—that is, when supply and demand interact—they create markets. As you have learned, in a pure market economy, markets handle the problem of scarcity. Markets ensure scarce resources, goods, and services are allocated to the people who can afford (and desire) to buy them. Naturally, when we study economics, we talk a lot about supply and demand. In fact, according to an old saying, if you teach a parrot to repeat, “supply and demand,” you will have created an economist. In this section on microeconomics, you will certainly have to read about supply and demand, but we won’t stop there. Supply and demand are only the beginning. Prices Without prices, markets would make little sense. Remember the barter economy? Imagine how frustrated you would be if you were trying to sell your house and you had to measure its value in potted plants to one prospective buyer and in dental cleanings to another. How would you know which was the better offer? How could you compare them? Prices eliminate this problem. With prices, we have a common measure for making exchanges. Prices are expressed in a consistent way—in terms of dollars, won, or what-not36—so people can use them to make rational decisions. 36 Or, technically, what-notes. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 28 To an economist, prices are especially important because people respond to changes in prices with changes in behavior. Sometimes, people shape their careers (or have their parents shape them) on the basis of what they expect the “prices” (salaries) will be for different jobs. Master’s of Low Wages When the Harvard Kennedy School accepted me to a two-year program leading to a Master’s in Public Policy, it sent me a brochure describing the career opportunities that lay ahead. Graduates were helping to build houses in Haiti, running for office in small towns, and volunteering at neighborhood schools. Inspiring! But the career statistics were oddly grim. The average salary for someone coming out of the Kennedy School was lower than that of someone from the undergraduate college. After a burst of panic, I realized it was a case of self-selection bias-----people choosing the Kennedy School most likely weren’t looking for high salaries as much as they were for the more meaningful pursuits that had drawn them to the program in the first place. Surely I could choose to attend and then find a more balanced career. Of course, after graduating, I started a nonprofit and stopped taking a salary. My parents probably wish I had gone to the business school. Now we’ll look into the meat of economics, supply and demand, to see what determines prices. Demand In the language of economics, “demand” is the relationship between the price of a good or service and the quantity demanded of that good or service—the quantity buyers are willing and able to buy. As its price decreases, the quantity demanded of it will increase. DEMAND SCHEDULE FOR TVS Price per Number of TVs 3D TV Demanded $1100 200 $1000 300 $900 500 $800 900 $700 1300 $600 1800 $500 2400 $400 3100 Put another way: the quantity demanded of any good or service increases as the price of the good or service decreases. This inverse relationship is called the Law of Demand. A demand schedule shows the various quantities of a good or service consumers are willing and able to buy at different prices. The table to the right is a demand schedule for 3D TVs. Notice how, at lower prices, such as $400 per TV, the quantity demanded is high; at the higher prices, like $1000 per TV, it is far lower. If we plot the data from a demand schedule into a graph, we form a demand curve. To the right is a curve representing demand for TVs. Now let’s look at the demand for another good: DECADOGS, a new line of scholarly hot dogs. The second table to the right is a demand schedule for DECADOGS. If we plot its data, we find the demand curve for DECADOGS. It turns out most demand curves are similar. Compare the demand curve for DECADOGS with that for TVs. Notice both are downward-sloping. On the left, both curves are high above the origin, but, as we move along either curve, from left to right, Demand for DECADOGS Price ($) .10 .25 .50 .70 1.00 2.00 Quantity Demanded 100 75 30 15 5 2 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 29 the curves move downward. The downward slope is a graphical representation of the law of demand: as price decreases, quantity demanded increases. One reason the demand curve slopes downward is the income effect. If a good’s price falls, consumers are left with more income to spend both on it and on other goods. To consumers, the price decrease feels like an increase in overall income. It results in a higher quantity demanded of that good—and of all other goods! Another reason the curve slopes downward is the substitution effect: as a good’s price falls, consumers choose it over other goods with a similar purpose. If beef becomes cheaper, you might buy less chicken and more beef; again, moving down in price means moving to the right on quantity. Demand vs. Quantity Demanded We must be clear about the difference between demand and quantity demanded. Every economics exam tests this pesky detail. Demand refers to the entire curve—to an entire set of prices and quantities. If price goes down, quantity demanded goes up—but the demand curve remains unchanged. We still face the same conditions—just at a new point on the curve. If price changes, there is movement along the curve until we land at a new quantity demanded. If demand changes, there is a movement of the demand curve. The whole curve will shift to the right or left. I know an economics teacher who throws a foam brick at anyone who claims that changes in price change demand. It’s less scary the second time—diminishing returns—but the lesson remains: demand and quantity demanded are not the same. When demand increases, the curve shifts to the right. At each possible price, the corresponding quantity demanded is higher. When demand decreases, the curve shifts to the left. Again, for each possible price, the corresponding quantity demanded is lower. A demand curve might shift for one of several reasons. Notice again that these reasons are different from a change in price or quantity, which would cause movement along the demand curve. Use the device INSECTS to remember them: ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 30 a change in consumer income a change in the number of consumers a change in consumer expectations a change in the prices of complementary or substitute goods a change in consumer tastes a change in the season Changes in Consumer Income Normally, when consumers have more money, they demand more of any given good. That is, an increase in consumer income will cause the demand curve to shift to the right. At each price along the new demand curve, consumers will be willing and able to buy greater quantities. If the demand for a good increases when consumer income increases, the good is said to be a normal good. A television is an example of a normal good; if you get a raise, you might buy a new, larger TV. Sometimes, when people have more money, they buy fewer of certain goods. When they have less money, they buy more of these goods. These are called inferior goods. You’ll discover inferior goods as soon as you live on your own for the first time. Ramen noodles are an inferior good. So are macaroni-and-cheese dinners (the kind in a box with little white envelopes full of bright orange cheese-powder). College students eat a lot of ramen noodles and macaroni-and-cheese. Some happen to like these foods. For the rest of us, what it comes down to is this: you can buy whole lot of them for a dollar. Many students go to school all day; they only work part-time, if at all, and for little pay. Students are also fairly new at the art of personal finance, and often find themselves strapped for cash when rent or tuition is due. That’s about the time when the demand for ramen and macaroni-and-cheese will shift to the right. Unsurprisingly, when student loan checks come in, students suddenly start eating out, and the demand for ramen decreases; it shifts to the left. Luxury goods include Ferraris and caviar. They are like normal goods in that people buy more of them as their incomes increase, but different in that, as people make more money, they spend a larger percentage of their income on them. (This should make sense, as you would spend none of your income on most of these—like private jets—until you were deliriously rich.) ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 31 Changes in the Number of Consumers The number of consumers in a market affects the demand curve. If half of the consumer market for DECADOGs suddenly perished of smallpox, the quantity demanded for DECADOGs at each price would decrease by half, so the demand curve for DECADOGS would shift to the left. A fall in population will usually shift the demand curve to the left, and a rise in population to the right. Changes in Consumer Expectations When Apple announces that, on August 1, iPads will go on sale for half the current price, most people will stop buying iPads until the price comes down. Only a few consumers, those desperate for iPads, will stay in the market for them at the current price. Meanwhile, because demand is falling, the current equilibrium price will actually decrease prior to the official price cut. Current demand will always decrease if consumers expect prices will be lower in the future. Similarly, if consumers expect that something is going to become more expensive in the future, they are more likely to buy it right away. This increases the number of consumers currently on the market, raising demand and leading to a higher equilibrium price. Current demand will always increase if consumers expect prices will be higher in the future. Economists conclude that consumer expectations are self-fulfilling prophecies. The belief that prices will increase leads prices to increase. The belief that they will fall leads them to fall. This analysis is referred to as the theory of rational expectations37. Changes in Prices of Substitutes and Complements A substitute good is one consumers are willing to use in place of another: Pepsi and Coke, iPhones and Android phones, bagels and English muffins, plastic bags and paper bags, etc. Even private colleges and public universities are substitute goods. When the price of a good increases, the quantity demanded of that good decreases—leaving more people looking for a replacement good (since presumably there was a reason they wanted the original good in the first place). This means the demand for the substitute good will increase, as the number of people in the market for it has increased. Suppose that, on hot days, you drink iced chai or lemonade. Both beverages cost the same amount. You usually choose chai because, like me, you like it better.38 But suppose the price of chai went up. You’d probably 37 This theory is also reflected in politics: when people expect a certain candidate to lose, they’re less likely to vote for him, making it more likely that he will lose. 38 I liked chai better, too, until overdosing in Dubai. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 32 buy less of it. To continue quenching your thirst, you’d buy more lemonade. You would join the population of people who buy lemonade. By increasing the number of lemonade consumers, you would have caused the demand curve for lemonade to shift to the right. A complementary good is one associated with another because the two goods are consumed together. Peanut butter and jelly are complements. Printers and toner cartridges are complements. If the price of a good increases, then the quantity demanded of the good will decrease, and the demand for the good’s complement will decrease as well, since fewer people will need it. Consider an example. You’re lounging in your luxury office at DECADOGS, Inc. You’ve just discovered a mustard stain on your shirt collar when your assistant charges into the office.39 You offer her a chair, but she refuses to sit. She places both hands on your desk and leans in. Between gasps, she whispers, “I just… received word… that… the price of hot dog buns… is… rising.” You jump from your seat. As CEO of DECADOGS, and an astute economist, you know it is bad news. You think, if the price of hot dog buns rises, then the quantity demanded will fall… which means people will eat fewer hot dog buns… which means they’ll need… nnoooo... fewer DECADOGS! You drop to your knees, lift your head and scream, “The demand curve will shift to the left!!!” Keep this in mind: a change in the price of a good will never change the demand for that good, but it can and often does change the demand for its substitutes and complements. Two goods are substitutes if they can replace one another. A price increase in a good causes an increase in demand for substitute goods. Two goods are complements if they go together. A price increase in a good causes a decrease in demand for complementary goods. Changes in Consumer Tastes Changes in the tastes and preferences of consumers can cause the demand curve to shift to the right or left. Advertising, social perceptions, the weather, and even medical research can play a part in this component of 39 They got the mustard out! ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 33 demand. If consumer taste changes to favor a good, then the demand for that good will increase—its demand curve will shift to the right. Tickle-Me-Elmos were once so popular as Christmas gifts that Americans literally threw punches as they fought to buy them for up to $300 each——twenty times their list price! Effective advertising and social pressure caused more consumers to join the population willing to pay $300 for a Tickle-Me-Elmo. For a short time, the demand curve shifted far to the right. The same phenomenon has repeated often in the toy industry: Wiis, Furbies, even, long ago, Cabbage Patch Kids. Sometimes, people expect it to occur, but it doesn’t—such as with Apple’s first iPhone. Some folks bought extras, planning to resell them on eBay. But no one was interested in buying them at a premium, as there were enough iPhones to go around. The Atkins Diet—which urged people not to eat carbohydrate-rich foods such as bread, pasta, and xiao long bao—caused a similarly drastic change in consumer tastes and preferences. It convinced many consumers to leave the population willing and able to buy and eat baked goods and spaghetti.40 The demand curves for bread shifted to the left. Seasonal Changes Some goods are more useful at some times of the year than at others. When a seasonal good is “in season”—that is, when it is most useful to consumers—demand for it will increase, and the demand curve will shift to the right. When it is “out of season,” the demand curve will shift to the left. Seasonal goods include things like ski equipment, parkas, Easter candy, Valentine’s Day cards, and swimwear. Who wants Christmas wrapping in July? Or Easter candy for Halloween? Supply In the language of economics, supply is the relationship between the price of a good or service and the quantity supplied of it. Mathematically, supply is a function that maps price to quantity supplied. Supply is not an actual number, quantity supplied is. SUPPLY SCHEDULE FOR TVS Price per TV $1100 $1000 $900 $800 $700 $600 $500 $400 Number of TVs Supplied 3100 2400 1800 1300 900 500 300 200 The general relationship between price and quantity supplied is the law of supply, which states that as the price of a good or service increases, the quantity supplied of it will also increase. We can say price has a positive relationship with quantity supplied because an increase in a good’s price will result in an increase in the quantity supplied, and vice-versa. A supply schedule shows the various quantities of a good or service that producers are willing and able41 to produce and make available for sale at each price within a range of prices. The table below is a supply 40 What would the impact be on the demand for Noodlebushes? The United States government also uses this phrase to decide if you are entitled to unemployment insurance: you need to be looking for a job and “willing and able” to start immediately. You can’t go on vacation and collect unemployment. 41 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 34 schedule for TVs. Notice that at the lower prices, like $400 per TV, the quantity supplied is low, whereas at the higher prices, like $1000 per TV, the quantity supplied is high. At any price greater than production cost, there is a producer that will supply a good (or service.) If the price is low, producers will usually make smaller quantities of it, because they can’t generate as much profit from each sale. The opportunity cost of producing the good becomes higher. If they can get away with charging more, producers will make a greater quantity of it. As with demand, if we plot the data from a supply schedule into a graph, we will form a supply curve. To the right is a curve for the supply of TVs. Recall that a demand curve is typically downwardsloping. Notice how the supply curve above is the opposite—it’s upward-sloping. A typical supply curve has a positive slope. Supply vs. Quantity Supplied As in the case of demand, we must be very clear about the difference between supply and quantity supplied. When price changes, there is a corresponding change in quantity supplied. That’s what the supply curve tells us. It answers the questions “What is the quantity supplied at price X?” and “What price will result in Y-units supplied?” If there is a price change, there is a movement along the supply curve until we land at a new quantity supplied. If supply changes, there is a movement of the supply curve. The whole curve will shift to the right or left. There are a number of reasons why the supply curve might shift. The main ones: a change in the cost of the factors of production a change in the technology used for production the expectation of a price change a change in the number of suppliers In the coming pages, we’ll discuss each of the factors that affect supply. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 35 Changes in the Costs of Factors of Production Economics assumes that producers supply goods and services in order to make a profit. (Profit can be defined very broadly to include social benefits that the producers find valuable; this helps explain why some people are willing to work in the non-profit sector.) If the factors of production become less expensive, the profit margin increases, so more producers grow willing to make the product. In perfect competition, new producers also enter the market. At each price along the supply curve, there will therefore be a greater quantity supplied— which means the supply curve will shift to the right. On the other hand, if the factors of production become more expensive, some producers will be unwilling to continue producing, so at each price along the supply curve, there will be a lower quantity supplied. The supply curve will shift left. Let’s go back to DECADOGS. If the price of lowquality meat goes up, so will your costs of producing DECADOGs; at any given price you will not be willing to sell as many as you did before. You might not have the dramatic meltdown you had during the hot dog bun crisis, but you will certainly need to call a strategy meeting to try to come up with ways of saving in other areas of production. Perhaps you can reduce processing time or use squirrels instead of more expensive beef. Until you can lower your production costs again, your supply curve will remain to the left of where it was originally. Technology When the technology used in production improves, suppliers can supply a greater quantity at each possible price: the supply curve will shift to the left. For example, suppose a bright intern at DECADOGS creates a new Dog-o-Lator, a machine that produces DECADOGs in half the time of the old process. With this new technology, DECADOGS, Inc. can supply twice as many DECADOGs at any given price. To reflect the sudden increase in quantity supplied, the supply curve will shift to the right. Expectation of a Price Change If suppliers expect the market price for their good or service to go up in the future, they will be less willing to supply it now (at the same time, remember, consumers will be more eager to buy it.) Suppliers will want to hold onto their product so they can have more of it to sell when the market selling price is higher. Before the price increase happens—and of course, there is the risk it won’t ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 36 happen—quantity supplied will decrease at each possible price. To reflect the change, the supply curve will shift to the left. On the other hand, if suppliers expect the market price of their good to decrease in the future, they’ll want to sell more of it now, while they can still sell it for the higher price. At each possible price along the supply curve, they’ll be willing to supply a higher quantity, so the supply curve will shift to the right. You might find it helpful to think like a supplier. If you sell pens and you expect the price to go up next week, you’ll hold onto your supply this week so you can sell more next week at a higher price. And if you have reason to believe the price of Tickle-Me-Elmos will go down next month, you’ll be willing to sell more at every price today, because you’ll probably make more money now than next month. Similar reasoning motivates day-before-Christmas sales. Number of Suppliers If there is an increase in the number of suppliers of a particular product, then at each possible price along the supply curve, there will be more suppliers who are willing and able to produce and sell. All along the curve, quantity supplied will increase. The supply curve will shift to the right. Similarly, a decrease in the number of suppliers will cause the supply curve to shift to the left. Suppose half the suppliers of bicycle wheels are hit with the bubonic plague. The plague also destroys all their shops and equipment. (Don’t ask how. It’s an example.) At every given price, quantity supplied decreases by about half, because there are only half as many suppliers who can produce and sell bicycle wheels. The supply curve shifts to the left. Market Equilibrium If we plot the supply and demand curves on one graph, the curves intersect. The point where they intersect is the point of market equilibrium. At this point, quantity supplied equals quantity demanded, so the market “clears.” ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 37 At market equilibrium, buyers purchase everything producers are willing to sell. Every unit produced is cleared out—warehouses are left empty. In this way, the interaction of supply and demand determines the market price. This interaction helps to allocate scarce resources, goods, and services. The equilibrium price and quantity are also called the market clearing price and clearing quantity. There are two components to market equilibrium. One is the exchange price, or the selling price. The other is the exchange quantity, or the quantity demanded and supplied—the total quantity of a particular good that is sold for the exchange price. You can use a graph of market equilibrium to predict the net effect of a shift in supply or demand on the market for a particular good. For instance, suppose you want to know what will happen to the macaroni-and-cheese market if the income of college students increases. Because macaroni-and-cheese is an inferior good, the increase in income will cause the demand curve to shift to the left, but it won’t affect supply. In the new equilibrium, the exchange price and quantity will be lower. Let’s consider another example: the hot dog bun shortage confronting DECADOGS, Inc. The price of hot dog buns rose, causing the demand for DECADOGs to shift to the left. The price change did not affect supply. In the new equilibrium, both the exchange price and quantity were lower: DECADOGs, like most hot dogs, are made of poor quality, low-grade meat. When the price of this meat went up, you had to reduce your supply of DECADOGs. Nothing happened to the demand curve, but the supply curve shifted to the left, resulting in a new equilibrium. In the new equilibrium, the exchange quantity was lower, but the exchange price was higher: When your intern at DECADOGS, Inc. came up with that new Dog-o-Lator, you were able to increase production of DECADOGs. After the supply curve shifted right, the exchange price fell—good news for customers—but the exchange quantity increased—good news for you. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 38 Now suppose you had just returned from overseeing the first run of the Dog-o-Lator when your assistant told you the price of hot dog buns was on the rise. Your supply curve had just shifted to the right. Your demand curve was suddenly shifting to the left. Without more details, the overall change in quantity exchanged would be ambiguous. There would be no way of knowing the new quantity. All we would know for sure is that, in the new equilibrium, the exchange price would be lower. Summarizing Equilibrium Changes When supply and demand move in different directions, the equilibrium price follows what happens to demand. If supply decreases and demand increases, price increases. If supply increases… If demand increases… If demand decreases… Equilibrium price change is ambiguous. Equilibrium quantity increases. Equilibrium price decreases. Equilibrium quantity change is ambiguous. Equilibrium price change is If supply Equilibrium price increases. When supply and demand ambiguous. decreases… Equilibrium quantity change move in the same direction, is ambiguous. Equilibrium quantity decreases. equilibrium quantity goes in that direction too. If both supply and demand increase, so does equilibrium quantity. Price and Wage Controls Sometimes—as the United States did during World War II—governments enact price and wage controls. They set maximum or minimum prices for a good or service. By definition, effective price controls interfere with market equilibrium. It can be tempting to impose a high minimum wage, to ensure everyone is paid enough to afford food and shelter, but such a policy can also result in consequences such as higher unemployment. Society must decide if those consequences are worthwhile. There are two main kinds of price controls. A price floor is a minimum price for which something may be sold. For a price floor to have an effect, it must be above the market equilibrium price. Since price is higher than at equilibrium, there will be less quantity demanded than supplied. The result: a surplus. A price ceiling is a maximum price for which something may be sold. A price ceiling must be set below the market equilibrium price to have any effect. The result of a price ceiling below the equilibrium price is a shortage, or an excess of quantity demanded over quantity supplied. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 39 Consider a minimum wage—an example of a price floor. It imposes a minimum price at which laborers may sell their labor. When a minimum wage is enacted, a surplus of labor results: there are more workers willing to work for a minimum wage and not as many employers willing to pay them. Indeed, there are usually workers who would be willing to work below the minimum wage but are no longer allowed to. Since labor factors into the cost of production, higher labor costs reduce supply. Price floors are often imposed on agriculture in the United States, to help keep farmers in business. The result: farmers grow more crops than consumers want. The government buys up the surplus and stores it, or sends it abroad as foreign aid. Price ceilings work the opposite way. They are common in the rental market. Some rent controls are outright limits; others restrict how quickly rent can increase. Rent controls distort the market. Current renters benefit from lower rent—but current landlords collect less rent than they otherwise could. They may avoid improving units or even use them for more profitable purposes—even illegal ones, such as methamphetamine labs! Would-be renters face a shortage of units; would-be landlords have less reason to purchase buildings, depressing property values. Those squeezed out may take part in a black market— one that works outside the law. Black markets were common in communist economies, such as the Soviet Union, and emerge in prisons for goods such as cigarettes. Black markets are referred to as the underground economy. Be careful not to confuse price floors and ceilings. If we put them on the same graph, they form an upsidedown house: the floor is above the ceiling.42 PRICE FLOORS ARE USUALLY HIGHER THAN THE EQUILIBRIUM PRICE. THEY LEAD TO A SURPLUS. PRICE CEILINGS ARE USUALLY LOWER THAN THE EQUILIBRUM PRICE. THEY LEAD TO A SHORTAGE. Look again at the graphs of price floors and ceilings. The arrows point at gaps where the floor and ceiling intersect supply and demand. Those gaps are the surpluses and shortages, respectively. Utility and Income Suppose you are at a bookstore trying to decide between economics books and autobiographies. Perhaps you gain 10 utils from each economics book you read, and four utils from each autobiography. In other 42 I’m sure this would be very uncomfortable. Economics isn’t always about common sense. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 40 words, you’ll get the same satisfaction from two economics books as you will from five autobiographies—20 utils in all. An economist would tell you that you are indifferent between the two combinations. Both offer the same total utility. How will you decide which combination to buy? As a normal person you would say that you would buy whichever combination costs you the least money, giving you the “best bang for the buck.” But as an economist, you’ll have to learn to say that you will buy at the point where your indifference curve intersects your budget line. An indifference curve is a graphical representation of the many ways in which two goods (or two activities, etc.) can bring you the same amount of happiness. If a curve sits close to the origin, the goods along the curve are not bringing you much satisfaction. If a curve is further from the origin, it means that all the possible combinations of the two goods are more satisfying than all the possible combinations on the curve closer to the origin. The indifference curves represent the utility you get from combinations of Mounds Bars and Almond Joys. You might notice the curves are, well, curved. They bow inward toward the origin. This is because economists have observed that people, in general, like variety. As in the case of Mounds and Almond Joy, sometimes you feel like a nut, and sometimes you don’t. Most people prefer a combination of two goods over a lot of only one good. Now look closely at curve A on the graph. At any point on this curve, your total utility is the same. You would be just as satisfied with five Mounds and one Almond Joy as you would be with two of each. On curve B, the story is the same. No matter which point you choose along the curve, you’ll be just as content as you would anywhere else along the curve. The difference between the two curves is that curve B is further from the origin, so your total utility along B is higher than along A. Recall that utility is a tricky and subjective matter of economics. We have no way of knowing how much more utility you’ll get from curve B than from A; we only know you will get more. Utility is just not something we can truly quantify. Something we can measure about utility is the marginal rate of substitution. This is the amount of one good you are willing to give up to get one more of the other good at a given point on an indifference ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 41 curve. On the graph, it is the slope of the indifference curve at a given point43. As you move from point x to point y, the marginal rate of substitution is 3, because you’ll give up three Mounds bars for just one Almond Joy. At point y, it is 1, and from point y to point z it is 1/3 (you give up 3 Almond Joys to get one Mounds). This should remind you a lot of the Production Possibilities Frontier. Unfortunately, when we walk into a store, we don’t simply grab all the candy bars we’d like. If that were the case, it would be very difficult to pick a point on an indifference curve. In the real world, we have to pay for our candy bars, and that’s part of how we decide what to buy. Suppose you have $2, and each kind of candy bar costs 50 cents. You can get 4 Mounds, or 3 Mounds and an Almond Joy, or 2 of each, and so on. If you plot all your purchasing possibilities onto a graph, the points form a budget line. Where an indifference curve represents what you want, your budget line represents what you can afford. A budget line is nearly always straight because the prices of goods are generally fixed. Everything to the right of the budget line is infeasible, and every point on it or under it is a potential point of consumption. The budget line also represents a slope on the curve, or a particular marginal rate of substitution. In this case, that rate of substitution is 1:1—as the prices are identical. In actuality, a budget line can have any slope. The graph shows your budget line for the $2 you plan to spend on Mounds and Almond Joys. According to your budget line, you just can’t have five of either bar. To determine how to maximize your utility with the $2 you plan to spend, you will have to buy at the point where one of your indifference curves is tangent to your budget line. If a curve crosses the line, it’s no good—there must still be another curve further out that touches your budget line and that you could therefore afford. As it turns out, the indifference curve that matters here is curve A. If there were another curve, closer to the origin than A, it would cross the budget line. Curve B, on the other hand, doesn’t even touch your budget line. It would make you happier, but you just can’t afford it. The budget line is tangent to curve A at point y. That is the point that will bring you the greatest satisfaction within your budget—and that, then, is where you should make your purchase. You should buy two of each bar. Indifference curves are a good lesson in thinking like an economist. 43 This, for all you calculus buffs, is d ( Mounds) d ( AlmondJoy) . – Craig ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 42 Elasticity Suppose that if you increased your study time 10%, your score would rise 30%. This would be a useful ratio to know. A ratio like this one measures the elasticity of your score based on your study time. Elasticity indicates how responsive one variable is to changes in another. In economics, we focus on elasticity of variables related to price. Ordinarily, elasticity refers to the relationship between a change in price or some other factor and the corresponding change in quantity demanded or supplied. The most common measure of elasticity is the price elasticity of demand, which describes how much quantity demanded changes when price does. A common way to calculate it is: PED = % change in quantity demanded % change in price If the PED for a good is greater than one, then the demand for that good is price elastic. This means quantity demanded changes a lot based on price. Maybe a 5% increase in price results in a 15% decrease in quantity demanded—a PED of 15/5, or 3. If PED is less than one, then demand is price inelastic. The percent change in quantity demanded is less than the percent change in price—for example, a 5% increase in price might result in a 2.5% decrease in quantity demanded—a PED of 2.5/5, or 1/2 . If it equals one, then demand is unit elastic with respect to price. A 10% increase in price leads to a 10% decrease in quantity demanded—a one to one relationship. If the PED is 0, then demand is perfectly inelastic with respect to price. A change in price has no effect on quantity demanded. And if the PED is infinite—that is, if a tiny change in price leads to a decrease of quantity demanded all the way to zero—then demand is perfectly elastic with respect to price. Our demand for the goods we find most necessary tends to be price-inelastic—a change in price is unlikely to stop us from buying them. “Necessary” goods include medicines, alpaca finger puppets, and salt. If the price of salt went up 20 percent, your demand for salt would be unlikely to change. Even if you noticed the price change, you would probably still prefer to pay a bit more for salt than to find a salt substitute. Conversely, if the price of salt went down, you probably wouldn’t increase your consumption of it very much. What could you do with more salt? Hamburger meat is an example of a non-necessary good. The demand for hamburger meat tends to be more price-elastic than the demand for salt. Hamburger meat is not that expensive, and many consider it a necessary part of their diets. But, because they have many substitutes, demand for hamburgers is more elastic than you might expect. If the price went up significantly, people could eat ostrich, chicken or even veggie burgers instead. These are all substitutes. So while the demand for food itself is inelastic, the demand for hamburger meat is not. There are three main reasons why the demand for a good might be price-inelastic: ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 43 A good is considered a “necessity.” Prescription drugs, for many people, are a necessity. A good has few substitutes. Until it was retired, there were very few close substitutes for the Concorde supersonic jet: you were stuck with it or with a much slower plane, like a Boeing 747. The price of a good represents a small portion of a consumer’s income. Salt is just not expensive enough for a person to stop buying it when the price goes up. However, a Lexus is expensive enough that if the price increases ten percent, a rational person will consider a different car. A supplier can benefit from understanding the price elasticity of the demand for his product. If demand is price-elastic, then he has to be careful about raising his price so much that he loses revenue. On the other hand, if a seller knows that demand is price-inelastic, then he has the power to increase his revenue simply by increasing his price. Some producers spend enormous amounts of money on advertising, hoping to convince their customers that their products have no substitutes. If consumers believe a product has no substitute, they will tolerate a price increase. Suppose you own a store that sells outdoor clothes and equipment. On average, you sell 200 pairs of Teva sandals per day for $60 per pair. You decide to raise your price to $70 per pair, hoping to increase your total revenue. After the price increase, you sell only 150 pairs per day. As you know, you can use this information to calculate the price elasticity of demand for Tevas in your store: PED (Tevas) = % change in quantity demanded % change in price = 200 pair - 150 pair 200 pair = $60 per pair - $70 per pair $60 per pair 0.25 = 1.4997 0.1667 As it turns out, demand for Tevas is price-elastic. You have to be careful about raising prices, because they could decrease quantity demanded so much that your store will actually earn less revenue. This leads to a second way to determine whether demand is elastic or inelastic: compare total revenue before and after a price change. In the example above, you were selling 200 pairs for $60 apiece, so you were earning $12,000 in revenue each day. After your price increase, you sold 150 pairs for $70 apiece, so you were earning only $10,500 in revenue per day. As a rule of thumb, if you raise prices and… … total revenue decreases, then demand is price-elastic. … total revenue increases, then demand is price-inelastic. … total revenue does not change, then demand is unit-price-elastic. … total revenue plunges to zero, then demand is perfectly price-elastic. … quantity demanded doesn’t change at all, then demand is perfectly price-inelastic. You increased prices and total revenue decreased, so you could have inferred the demand for Teva sandals was price-elastic. Had revenue increased, it would have meant demand was price-inelastic. The third way to determine PED is just to look at the demand curve. If the curve is vertical, demand is perfectly price-inelastic. If it is horizontal, demand is perfectly price-elastic. And if it’s perfectly diagonal, demand is unit-elastic with respect to price: Here’s a memory aid to help you analyze the price-elasticity of a demand curve: Brick walls are vertical, and very inelastic. Inelastic demand curves are more vertical, like brick walls. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 44 Elastic demand curves are more horizontal. They are like a rubber band you would shoot at somebody. Market Structures As you know, a market is a mechanism that brings buyers and sellers together. Some of the examples of markets we have mentioned have included eBay, supermarkets, and farmers’ markets. To continue our discussion, we are going to expand that definition. In microeconomics, we define a market as all the buyers and sellers of one particular product or service. For example, there is a market for shampoo, a market for travel guides, etc. We can then classify each market by its market structure, which is defined by several characteristics. One is the number of buyers and sellers in the market. Some markets have only one seller. Others have many of them. Some have only one buyer and others have many buyers. The second defining characteristic of market structures is the sort of competition among suppliers. In some markets, suppliers engage in price competition, or the raising and lowering of prices, to increase revenue or attract customers. In others, individual suppliers cannot change their prices, so they must engage in non-price competition. A third feature of market structures is the uniformity of the product from one seller to the next. In some markets, the product is exactly the same from one producer to the next. In others, there is only one seller because his or her product is so unique. Another feature of market structures is the presence of barriers to entry. If there are no barriers to entry, sellers can easily enter or leave the market. This greatly affects the degree of competition. We’ll explore four distinct market structures. In the coming pages, they’re presented in the order of most competitive to least competitive, as they are seen on the spectrum below: Perfect Competition (Most Competitive) Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Monopoly (Least Comeptitive) Perfect Competition The most classic example of perfect competition is the market for wheat. There are many farmers selling an indistinguishable product; everyone has to charge the same amount, because there is no way to set apart one kind of wheat from another. New farmers can easily set up wheat fields, and existing wheat farmers can easily leave the market and use their land to cultivate something else. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 45 A perfectly competitive market has numerous buyers and sellers. There are no barriers to entry or exit, which means suppliers can join or leave the industry whenever they want. The product in a perfectly competitive market is completely homogenous. Consumers don’t have any preference for one supplier’s product over another, because they are all identical. Finally, a perfectly competitive market assumes that all participants have perfect information, a condition in which all buyers and sellers, actual and potential, have equal and free access to knowledge about the price and availability of the product and about one another. Examples of perfectly competitive markets include nearly all commodities, such as farm products or natural resources, like gold or coal. In perfect competition, the price is set at the market level based on supply and demand. Any individual firm has a negligible impact on the market and must sell at whatever the market price happens to be. The demand for any one firm’s product is perfectly elastic with respect to price. The demand curve for a firm is perfectly horizontal. Consumers have no preference for one supplier’s product over another, so if a supplier raises its price, consumers will take their business elsewhere. In perfect competition, firms are forced to be price takers; they “take” their price from the market. If a producer raises his price, consumers will no longer buy from him. On the other hand, if a producer lowers his price, he will only cost himself revenue he could have had by selling at the market price. Thus, producers have no incentive to change their prices in order to compete. Also, because there are so many buyers in a perfectly competitive market, a firm can sell, at the market price, as much of the good or service as it wants to. A firm has only to analyze its costs to decide how much to produce. Monopolistic Competition Monopolistic competition is the second-most Debate it! competitive market structure. It features many Resolved: That companies should not be allowed to buyers and sellers, and relatively few barriers to exaggerate distinctions between their products. entry. The products are all similar, but each seller tries to convince consumers that its product is unique. To the degree that they succeed, the sellers are price makers. Rather than the horizontal, perfectly-elastic demand curve of perfect competition, in monopolistic competition each seller faces a somewhat downward-sloping demand curve. They can choose different price points at which different quantities of their product will be demanded—but demand is more elastic than in a monopoly because close substitute goods exist. Each producer tries to achieve product differentiation. Some products are made to seem different from (and presumably better than) their rivals in taste, color, texture, or packaging. Most product differentiation down to effective branding. If advertising and word-of-mouth convince consumers that a product has no close substitutes, they will tolerate higher prices. Two brands of pain medication aren’t ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 46 very different, but you’d never know it from the television commercials. One bottle of ketchup is a lot like any other, but most people still have a favorite brand—say, Heinz. The more a monopolistically competitive firm differentiates its product, the less price-elastic its demand will be, and the more control it will have over the price it can charge. In other words, each firm in monopolistic competition is trying to create a monopoly over its own version of a product. Oligopoly In an oligopoly, there are only a few, large sellers and many buyers. Their products are either homogeneous or only slightly different. Because there are so few sellers and each is large, they tend to be interdependent; each one’s decisions affect all the others. Barriers to entry are steep in an oligopoly. Natural barriers to entry exist when economies of scale favor an established firm that has already developed the infrastructure and client base to realize the savings of large-scale production. For instance, it would be expensive to start a new steel company, and it would need to begin by producing less steel than its established competitors. Artificial barriers to entry include patents, government regulation, import quotas and tariffs. If three firms have patents for all the ways to manufacture anti-depression medication, it can be difficult for others to enter the market until those patents have expired, even if the drugs are inexpensive to produce. Similarly, the United States government does not permit Australian-owned Qantas Airlines to sell tickets on its flight from Los Angeles to New York—it can only pick up fuel, not passengers. If airlines were completely deregulated, there would be no such constraint. In an oligopoly, the demand for any firm’s product is kinked. This model of oligopoly pricing was developed during the Great Depression. The economist Paul Sweezy noticed that, while most prices plummeted during the Great Depression, the prices of goods produced by oligopolist industries remained stable. The kinked demand curve helps to explains why this is so. This model concludes that if one firm lowers its prices, other firms will follow, but no one will follow an increase in price. The firms in an oligopoly are limited to mostly nonprice competition. For example, an airline might offer more comfortable business class seating or an in-flight meal. Of course, it could also lower its fares to attract business, and airlines often do, but this usually initiates a price war: competing airlines simply lower their prices too, and, in the end, all of them risk losing revenue. To stay competitive, each firm watches the pricing and non-price incentives offered by the other firms. Oligopolistic firms that discuss pricing with one another in order to maximize profits are creating a cartel—which is illegal in the United States and in most of the world. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 47 The markets for U.S. domestic cars, breakfast cereals, and major airlines are examples of oligopolies. Monopoly A monopoly is a market in which there is only one seller of a product with no close substitutes. Any consumer who wants the product must buy from the sole seller. The barriers to entry into a monopoly are steep. They can come about for various reasons, each of which defines a different kind of monopoly. Natural monopolies develop in markets with high capital investment costs—such as public utilities, gas pipelines, or railroads. Imagine the fixed cost of building high speed railroad tracks for the entirety of China. It would be very expensive for a second company to enter the market and lay down its own set of tracks. Similarly, it would be very expensive for a second electric utility company to string power lines to all the houses in a city. Exclusive ownership of a natural resource can also produce a monopoly. Suppose you control the only source of water on a desert planet. Everyone in the region has to buy their water from you. You have total market power, since there are no real substitutes for water and no alternate sources. In the real world, the most famous example of this phenomenon is in the market for diamonds. One firm, DeBeers, controlled 80% of the world’s diamond production until the year 2000. While 80% was not a complete monopoly, it was a large enough share to give De Beers tremendous power over the diamond market.44 Creative Destruction Yes, it would be impractical for a second company to string power lines to all the houses in a city-----but a bright entrepreneur might come up with a way for houses to power themselves, perhaps through home microfusion devices. Such an innovation might put a traditional power company out of business. Later in the resource, you’ll learn the term for this kind of total market upheaval: creative destruction. The market price of widgets is $5, but some consumers are willing to pay more. When they buy widgets for $5, they pay less than they would be willing to. This money they are saving is the consumer surplus. A monopoly reduces quantity and raises the price to maximize producer surplus. The result is reduced consumer surplus and a deadweight loss. Deadweight loss is utility lost to both the consumer and the producer. Governments can also authorize monopolies in 44 They also had complete control over diamond slogans. In the 1940s, they coined the phrase Diamonds are Forever. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 48 certain markets. In a technological monopoly, a firm is the sole seller of a product because no one else has the technology to produce it—and it stays that way because the government grants patents to protect the ownership of the technology. For example, the government grants drug companies patents that prevent other companies from copying their drugs for 20 years. These temporary monopolies end when the patents expire, allowing rivals to manufacture generic versions of the drugs. Sometimes, the government creates an artificial monopoly—as when it granted the Postal Service a monopoly on door-to-door mail. UPS and FedEx can deliver packages to front doors, but not letters into mailboxes. The government authorizes such a monopoly when it has a special interest in a market. In this case, it wants to make sure that everyone has access to mail service. A monopoly firm has market power; it is a price maker. Of course, the monopoly still confronts a downward-sloping demand curve. A higher price means fewer units sold. But the monopoly creates all the supply47 in the market. It decides the quantity to produce, which determines the price at which a product is sold. A monopoly can pick the level of output that maximizes its own profits. Economists point to three main problems with monopolies. The first is contrived scarcity, which occurs when a monopoly limits production so it can charge a higher price. Suppose a monopoly that produces towels 45 Electric utilities Many state governments authorize a single electric utility to operate as a monopoly. In exchange, the utility agrees to let the state set its prices. The state sets a price a few percentage points above the utility’s costs, guaranteeing it a specific rate of return. But what if a technological advance could lower the cost of electricity production? Should the utility invest in it? If the state forces the firm to keep the original rate of return, then, after the utility makes the investment, the state will lower the price it is allowed to charge. Assuming people’s consumption of electricity is relatively price-inelastic, the utility’s profit won’t change much at all.45 Suppose it weren’t forced to adhere to its original rate of return. What if the state were to set a price and then allow the utility to keep any profits from innovations? The company would have an incentive to develop better technology. On the other hand, the consumer wouldn’t necessarily benefit, because market prices might remain the same even as the utility’s marginal cost decreased. Should the state look out for consumers, or for the utility? A hybrid solution may be the answer. 46 The Patent Wars: Apple vs. Samsung In summer 2012, a California jury handed down a massive verdict in a patent lawsuit between Samsung and Apple. Samsung, the jury decided, had maliciously violated a number of Apple patents on the look and feel of its flagship product, the iPhone. From an economics perspective it’s worth considering the market implications. Smartphones are an example of monopolistic competition: there are a fair number of vendors producing reasonably similar products-----IPhones, Blackberries, Windows Phones, Android phones, etc.-----and the barriers to entry, while high, are not impossible to scale. (Mozilla, for instance, is about to release the first Firefox-based smartphones.) By defending patents on very basic aspects of the iPhone-----for example, rounded corners and pinch-to-zoom-----Apple is attempting to raise those barriers to entry and to strengthen its ‘‘mini-monopoly’’ within the larger market. At the same time, imagine if the first car company had patented something as basic as the steering wheel: that might have seriously hurt market innovation and made it difficult for consumers to switch between car companies. (It would be tough for someone growing up driving a car with a steering wheel to switch to a car driven with a joystick.) Some critics argue that certain patents come at the cost of public welfare-----and that the system is broken, granting patents too easily on innovations that are too vague. If the demand for electricity were very price-elastic, then many more consumers might purchase a lot more electricity—so even the same rate of return might produce more total profit. 46 Let’s Go travel guides are written by Harvard students. Let’s Go presents its writers with the average airfare to different destinations. If a researcher finds a cheaper rate, she can buy her own ticket. She then splits the savings with Let’s Go. 47 It is said to “face the entire demand curve.” ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 49 could sell 1,000 towels for $12 apiece, profiting $1 per towel. Or, it could sell 800 for $14 apiece, profiting $3 per towel. If the firm were in a more competitive market, it would have to sell at a lower price or consumers would choose another supplier. As a monopoly, it can opt to sell fewer units at a higher price, making $2,400 profit. The second problem with monopolies is deadweight loss. A monopoly will try to maximize its own producer surplus—taking it from the consumer surplus. But some surplus is simply lost. The vanished surplus is the welfare loss due to monopoly. A third problem is X-inefficiency. Monopolies have less incentive than firms in other market types to reduce costs, and may end up using resources inefficiently. They lack the competition that would drive out inefficient firms. Some economists believe monopolies do enjoy dynamic efficiency, or more internal innovation. For decades, the researchers at Bell Labs could perform world-changing research (they invented the laser!) because they were funded by a monopoly, AT&T. Smaller firms would not have had the luxury to support such innovation. The Production Decision In theory, all firms aim to maximize profit. A firm must produce up to the point where the marginal revenue from selling one more unit does not exceed the marginal cost of producing it. Hence, firms produce the quantity at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost, or MR=MC. Even monopolies are guided by this rule. We can find the point where MR=MC by plotting the marginal revenue and marginal cost curves together and seeing where they intersect. For a firm in perfect competition, the marginal revenue of every unit sold is always equal to the market price. A perfectly competitive firm is a price taker: it must take the market price of the good for every unit sold. If the market price is $5, selling an additional unit always brings in $5 of marginal revenue. These illustrations show the production decision faced by a firm in perfect competition----one with no control over the price it can set. Marginal revenue always equals market price, PE. For nearly all firms, marginal cost varies with each unit. At first, marginal cost is high because to produce just one unit, a factory has to be set up and a minimum amount of staff has to be hired. Materials have to be bought. But as a firm produces more units, marginal cost will decrease. Eventually, the marginal cost will begin to rise again, as per the law of diminishing marginal returns. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 50 Stated another way: there is a point at which additional units of resources will produce fewer and fewer units of output. The cost for every additional unit of output rises. Price Discrimination Next time you take a flight, look at the person squeezed in next to you.48 The odds are good he paid a different amount for his ticket than you did. He might be a business traveler paying extra to take a oneway flight, while you’re flying on a web special requiring you to stay overnight on Saturday and fly home on the Sunday red-eye. Or he might be a friend of an employee flying standby for next-tonothing—but risking not having a seat if the plane is full. Airlines aren’t alone in charging different people different prices. Popular restaurants offer early bird specials to lure people in for an early dinner—because they can only handle so many diners later in the evening. Movie theaters offer cheaper matinees for the same reason: to fill seats at times when they would be empty. Restaurants working with GroupOn offer 50% discounts to customers willing to pay for a certain dollar amount of food in advance—betting that people buying GroupOn vouchers would be unlikely to visit their restaurants otherwise. The demand curve shows that, for any good, some people are willing to spend a lot, and others much less. Take a second look at the consumer surplus diagram for widgets. Of the 100 people able and willing to buy widgets for $5 each, some would be willing to buy them for $6, or $7, or even $9.99 each. If a producer could charge each person the highest price he or she was willing to spend, it would radically increase its profit. It would do even better if it could also charge some less than $5— thus, the early bird dinner. Some critics believe price discrimination results in some people unfairly paying more than others; many economists think it helps create a more socially efficient market. Your position on this may depend on whether you’re in seat 19K for $29 or in seat 19L for $920. The Institutions of a Market Economy In market economies, strong institutions help individuals and groups achieve their goals. An institution can be an organization, a practice, or even a code of laws. Important institutions include: • • • • • financial intermediaries (banks, etc.) labor unions corporations legal systems property rights We will focus here on financial intermediaries, labor unions, and property rights. 48 Don’t look too long. It’s bad airplane manners. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 51 Financial Intermediaries A financial intermediary is an institution that stores money that firms and individuals are saving, using it to make loans to or to invest in other individuals and firms that need money. We can divide financial intermediaries into three major categories: depository institutions contractual savings institutions investment intermediaries You are probably more familiar with depository institutions than with other intermediaries. Depository Institutions Banks Savings and loan associations Credit unions Contractual Savings Institutions Insurance companies Pension funds Government retirement funds Investment Intermediaries Finance companies Mutual funds Money market funds Depository institutions accept deposits from customers and in turn pay interest to customers for the use of their funds. To earn a profit, depository institutions invest the funds they have collected. They earn profits on those investments—more profit than what they pay their depositors in interest. Some examples of depository institutions are banks, savings and loan associations, and credit unions. Depository institutions are integral to a market economy because they enable people to smooth consumption over time; that is, with their help, people can save for the future and borrow money to make investments in the present. A contractual savings institution is one that acquires funds periodically according to some kind of contractual arrangement, and, in turn, invests those funds to earn interest. Contractual savings institutions include insurance companies, pension funds, and government retirement funds. You’re probably most familiar with insurance companies. An insurance company will collect a premium from its customers, called policyholders. In exchange, the company promises to pay certain benefits in the event that something happens—perhaps to cover medical bills if a person is hurt, or to pay for a home destroyed in a fire. To earn a profit, the company adjusts its premiums based on careful predictions and makes long-term investments with the funds it holds. Labor Unions Workers may band together in labor unions to increase their market power as labor suppliers. Union members typically earn more than non-union workers doing the same job. They also tend to receive better benefits, such as health care and vacation time. Labor union membership peaked in the United States in the 1940s and has been declining more or less ever since. About 12% of workers in the United States belong to unions today. Trade and craft unions are comprised of Labor Unions and Company Competitiveness workers with a common skill. Such unions date Critics of American labor unions claim they lock employers back to the guilds of the Middle Ages; they into expensive contracts that make them uncompetitive in the restrict supply by imposing rules around face of foreign competition and fast-changing markets. licensing and apprenticeship. Economists view professional associations such as the American Bar Association (ABA) as trade unions. They restrict membership, and they enable members to earn higher fees for services. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 52 Industrial unions bring together all the workers in a given industry. For example, an autoworkers’ union might cover all workers in the auto industry—from welders to painters. Public employees’ unions consist of government employees. In the United States, nearly all public school teachers belong to such unions—including the Chicago teachers’ union that recently went on strike, generating national headlines in September 2012—as do police officers and other public servants. Labor unions engage in collective bargaining to negotiate wages, hours, and benefits with employers. Collective bargaining is effective at securing better deals because it limits the ability of the employer to divide and conquer employees and new hires. In other words, labor unions have more market power. When negotiations with an employer go sour, labor unions might call for a strike. Striking union members refuse to work until their demands are met. Those who don’t honor the strike are derogatively dubbed “scabs.” Scabs might suffer payback in the future. Strikes can backfire when companies hire temporary replacement workers to stay in operation—or when they annoy consumers so much that public sentiment turns against the labor union. Picketing generally occurs in conjunction with a strike. When workers picket, they patrol outside their workplace, carrying signs and shouting slogans. Picket lines can target both customers and other workers. Picketing is legal, but the government can restrict the time, place, and number of picketers, as it has sometimes led to violent confrontations. Watch it on YouTube In 1981, the Professional Air Traffic Controllers Organization launched a strike, grounding most air travel in the United States. President Reagan reacted swiftly-----giving the controllers 48 hours to return to work or be replaced. Watch footage of the strike and of Reagan’s reaction here: http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=e5JSToyiyr8 Property Rights Private property rights are essential in a market economy. When people have property rights, they can decide whether to use, rent, or sell the resources, goods, and services they own or produce. They reap the benefits and suffer the costs, so are likely to use property more carefully and productively. We can divide goods into two categories, according to how they are owned: Private goods are goods or resources owned by private individuals or groups of private individuals. When there are clearly-defined and well-enforced property rights in an economic system, the owners of private goods may use their property however they choose. Private goods are said to be excludable because owners have the power to exclude others from using them. I can exclude someone from typing on my laptop. Private goods are also said to be rival because people will compete to own them. If there are only five Nintendo Wiis for sale at Wal-Mart and 800 people are there to buy them, 795 are going to be disappointed. A public good is one that, once produced, is equally available to all people, regardless of whether they paid for its production. One example of a public good is national security. The United States spends about $1000 annually per person on national defense. No matter what country you live in, you can’t ask the government for your national defense money in cash and tell it to forget about defending you. Once your neighbors are protected, so are you. Some other examples of public goods include the atmosphere, national security, breathable air, and national parks. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 53 The Tragedy of the Commons is a story that serves as a reminder for why we need private property rights or regulation. Hundreds of years ago, there were open pastures in Europe called “commons”. People brought their animals to graze in the commons. In fact, the term ‘commoner’ referred to people who depended on the commons. Since none owned the commons, they did not worry about the cost of overusing them; in fact, each family had an incentive to bring as many animals as possible. The result was the depletion of the commons. Consider an example that involves eating animals instead of animals eating. Suppose a group of people goes to a steakhouse for dinner with the understanding that they will split the bill evenly. Each member has an incentive to order something expensive, since the additional cost will be split among everyone. If everyone obeys this incentive, everyone’s bill will be much higher. If only a few people obey it, they exploit the others at the table. When you reap the benefits of a public good without paying for it, you are a free rider—or a free loader. Property rights are one solution to this free rider problem. In Europe, open pastures gave way to enclosures. People who own a resource have an incentive to use it responsibly. Another solution is regulation: the government can either ban harmful behavior or can actually produce public goods. Private Property Protection in the United States In the United States, an owner’s rights to private property are protected by the Constitution. The Fifth Amendment holds that “No person shall… be deprived of life, liberty, or property without due process of law.” Due process refers to a consistently applied and fair legal proceedings. Laws also protect non-tangible forms of property through copyrights, patents, and trademarks. All three help to protect human ideas, or intellectual property. A copyright is a form of protection afforded to the creators of “original works of authorship,” such as economics resource guides. It protects the author’s right to control “expression” of the work, which includes reproduction, distribution, public performance, or display. There are several exceptions to this right. Nonowners are legally entitled to fair use, which means they can use “original works” for purposes such as teaching and news reporting. Also, the law provides for compulsory license, which means the owner of material can sometimes be required to license it. Patents vs. Copyright Both patents and copyrights protect intellectual property. To distinguish these two terms, consider a physics textbook. Probably none of the ideas in the book-----say, those related to circuits-----are protected by patent. Introductory physics has been around for a while; Galileo’s laws of motion are public domain. But the book itself is copyrighted: that particular expression of those ideas is protected. This means that after taking the class, you are free to write your own textbook on those same ideas. But you must write your book from scratch. As we saw in studying monopolies, a patent is a form of protection the government grants innovators for their new products and designs. A patent offers exclusive rights to the production, use, and sale of an invention for a specified period (usually 20 years, though design patents—essentially patents on the look of something—only last 14). A trademark is a unique commercial mark or symbol, such as the “swoosh on nearly everything made by Nike. Names of products can be trademarked, as long as they are somewhat original. For example, Intel used to name computer chips with numbers: 286, 386, 486. Because numbers are not original, they could not be trademarked. Competitors such as AMD and Cyrix soon manufactured compatible ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 54 chips using similar numbers. In the early 1990s, Intel named its newest chip the “Pentium” and trademarked the term immediately. Competitors were forced to look for their own snazzy names, such as AMD’s Athlon. Short marketing phrases can also be trademarked, such as McDonald’s “I’m lovin’ it”—or DemiDec’s “We do our best, so you can do yours.” Trademarks cannot be used by non-owners without permission. In early 2007, Apple was sued by Cisco for announcing the “iPhone”— Cisco already had a trademark on a product of the same name for making calls over computers. Apple quickly settled the lawsuit and continued selling the iPhone. Types and Nature of Income For most of us, the income we earn is determined by the value of the resources, goods, or services we sell. There are four categories of income. Each corresponds to a different kind of resource. If the resource you sell is your labor, you earn a wage. Your wage is a function of the market value of the thing you produce, how good you are at doing your job, and the condition of the labor supply. Typically, “wage” is represented as the amount of money earned in exchange for an hour of labor, regardless of whether you are paid by the hour or by a fixed salary. If you sell a natural resource, you earn rent. In economics jargon, “rent” has a far broader meaning than the monthly payment made for an apartment. Pure economic rent is the total payment to a factor of production whose supply curve is perfectly inelastic. Land is one such factor. There is only so much land to go around, no matter what the price. This is why the supply curve is inelastic: as price increases, quantity supplied of land (barring colonization of a new planet) cannot increase. Economic rent refers to the difference between a payment to a factor of production and the factor’s opportunity cost. Economic rent is any payment made to the owner of a factor of production above the amount necessary to keep that it involved in the desired occupation. If it would take $15 an hour to keep someone working for you, and you pay her $25 an hour, the extra $10 an hour is economic rent. If you supply… You earn… Labor Natural Resources Capital Entrepreneurship Wage Rent Interest Profit If you sell or rent capital resources, you earn interest. The term “interest” also refers to the money you earn when you deposit funds in a bank, or that you spend to borrow funds. In this context, though, interest is a type of income. You earn it in exchange for capital resources. If you provide entrepreneurial resources, the income you earn is profit. There are different measures of profit, accounting profit and economic profit. When we use the term profit in everyday conversation, we usually mean accounting profit, or total revenue minus total cost. Consider an entrepreneur who opens a cafe that costs $100,000 to operate the first year and earns $106,000 in revenue. His accountant congratulates him on his $6,000 in accounting profit. However, we can measure economic profit by taking the difference between total revenue and economic cost. Economic cost considers not just accounting but also opportunity cost. Unlike an accountant, an economist will remind the entrepreneur he could have made a 6.5 percent annual return had he simply put his money in a savings account. “Therefore,” she would tell him, “I’m afraid you made no economic profit. In fact, you have an economic loss of $500—or even more, if you could have gotten a different job while earning the $6,500 in interest. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 55 Factor Markets and Derived Demand A factor market is a market for any of the factors of production. In free market and mixed market economies, there are factor markets for natural resources, capital, labor, and entrepreneurship. In its economic reforms of the last 30 years, China has aimed to create and regulate these markets. In a factor market, firms demand resources. Households or other firms supply those resources. The demand in any factor market is said to be derived demand, because it is derived from the demand for every final good or service the resource is used to produce. The total demand for any resource is the sum of the demand for that resource in each of its possible uses. For example, the demand for lumber is the sum of the demand for lumber used to make pencils, plus the demand for lumber used to make houses, plus the demand for lumber used for firewood, and so forth. Remember that demand curves for most goods and services slope downward—the higher the price, the lower the quantity demanded. In the same way, the demand curve for any of the factors of production is also downward-sloping. As the price of a resource falls, quantity demanded increases: firms are willing and able to buy more of it. The Labor Market The labor market is a factor market. The demand for labor is derived demand: it is the sum of the demand for all the labor needed to produce every good and service— pencils, potatoes, pistols, Porsches, etc. We’ll focus on the demand for one type of labor: economists. This is like any other supply and demand curve, but the price is the wage rate and the quantity is the employment level. In the market for economists, the supply curve represents the number of economists willing and able to work at each possible wage rate, “W.” The wage rate is the cost a firm must pay in exchange for one hour of labor. The labor supply curve is upward-sloping, because more economists will want to work for a higher wage. The demand curve for economists represents the total number of economists firms are willing and able to hire at each possible wage rate. The economist demand curve is downward-sloping for a few reasons. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 56 As a firm hires more economists, later hires add less value than early hires—an example of the diminishing marginal productivity of labor. The economists can only analyze so much information, no matter how many of them there are. In fact, as more of them get together, they start arguing about their theories. It takes them longer to reach consensus. Remember Price Discrimination? Just as companies might want to charge different customers different prices, they might want to pay different wages to different economists. If the government of Kazakhstan were hiring an economist, perhaps economists from less prestigious universities would be paid less-----or those willing to relocate to Kazakhstan would be paid more. A second reason the demand curve slopes downward is the substitution effect. Rather than pay high salaries to several average economists, a firm might find it more cost-effective to hire two top-notch, pricy economists, and a number of cheap research assistants to help them. The firm has the option to substitute cheaper labor options for more expensive ones. The third reason: as the wage paid to economists rises, the prices of goods and services provided by their employers will also rise to reflect the higher cost of production. Consumers will be less willing and able to buy those goods and services, so quantity demanded of the good or service will decrease, and the quantity demanded of economists will decrease in turn. Because the “scale” of demand has changed, this is called the scale effect.49 Wage Rates In general, wages include hourly rates and salaries that firms pay in exchange for labor. More specifically, the wage rate is the amount a firm must pay for one hour of labor, regardless of whether the laborer is paid by the year (in the form of a salary) or by the hour. We can use the real wage rate to compare wages from different time Nominal Wage periods. The real wage rate is the wage rate adjusted for changes in how Real Wage = much money is worth over time—in other words, adjusted for inflation. Price Level The nominal wage rate is the rate actually paid to the worker—not adjusted for inflation. If inflation is high, nominal wages could skyrocket without real wages changing very much at all. Later in this resource, we will discuss inflation and the price level. For now, just know that, to determine the real wage, we divide the nominal wage by the price level. The Hiring Decision A profit-maximizing firm will decide how much labor to hire in the same way a consumer will determine how much to consume: the firm will conduct a benefit-cost analysis. Firms often do this explicitly, while consumers may do so less consciously. Every additional hour of labor produces a little more product for a firm. The marginal benefit to a firm of one more labor hour is the output produced by this hour of labor—multiplied by the revenue earned from selling that output. The actual output of an additional labor hour is the marginal product of labor (MPN); the revenue generated by this output is the marginal revenue product (MRP). Marginal revenue product is found by multiplying MPN by the product’s market price: MRP Marginal Revenue Product 49 = MPN Marginal Product of Labor x P Price It might also be called the “boomerang” effect, except economists don’t use fun terms like boomerang. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 57 Firms maximize profit by producing at the point where marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue. Beyond this point, a unit would cost more to produce than the revenue it would generate. In the same way, a firm maximizes output by hiring at the point where the marginal cost of labor is equal to its marginal benefit—in other words, where the wage rate is equal to the marginal revenue product: W Wage Rate MPN Marginal Product of Labor = x P Price Human Capital Development and Labor Productivity The production process converts the factors of production into goods and services. Productivity is a measure of the efficiency of production. It is expressed as a ratio of a specific output to a specific input. In a widget factory, the output might be widgets, and the input might be labor hours. The productivity of laborers in the factory could be expressed in terms of “widgets per labor hour.” Labor productivity is the most frequently-used measure of productivity. It measures the output of a unit of labor input. There are two ways to improve labor productivity. One is to improve physical capital. This can mean replacing a slow computer with a faster one or buying a printing press that makes fewer errors. When laborers are better-equipped, they tend to be more productive. The second is to invest in human capital. Human capital includes laborers’ knowledge, training, skills and experience. Workers who are better-educated or more skilled tend to be more productive (though recent studies also show workers who have faster Internet connections tend to procrastinate more). Labor Productivity Suppose two workers each work eight hours in a widget factory one day: = 16 labor hours At the end of the day, the two workers have produced a total of four widgets: Labor productivity is a ratio of output to input. In the widget factory, labor productivity is equal to four widgets per 16 labor hours, or one-fourth widget per labor hour: = per labor hour 16 Labor Hours Returns on Investment in Education One way to invest in your own human capital is to become more educated. Those who are more educated tend to make more money. In the United States, the average 35-year-old male who has completed four years of college earns about $25,000 per year more than the average 35-year-old man who completed only high school. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 58 Economists debate why the better-educated are better-paid. The most intuitive explanation is that education increases productivity. In some fields, like engineering, medicine, and teaching, this is true. But how much does a bachelor’s degree from Yale in Latin increase an office administrator’s productivity? Why would an employer prefer to hire her over a high school graduate? Read it Online The recent economic crisis has made it hard for college graduates in the United States to find jobs-----but the situation is much worse in China, where hundreds of new universities are churning out millions of college graduates who are unable to capitalize on their education. Check out these articles for more: http://www.nytimes.com/2010/12/12/world/asia/12beijing.html http://blogs.wsj.com/chinarealtime/2010/11/22/value-of-achinese-college-degree-44/ The answer may be that higher education also acts as a screening device or a signal. Even if the college degree is unrelated to the job, it still screens out non-college-graduates who may be, on average, less inclined to work hard and to succeed. The office administrator probably had to do well in high school and on standardized tests to get into college, especially an elite college like Yale or Princeton. Rather than screen all applicants for promptness, ability to learn, and willingness to follow directions, employers can assume a college-educated person already has these qualities. If your parents are ever wondering if it is worth sending you to Amherst to study literature, remind them of this. Other Factors That Influence Income In addition to education, other factors influence income. My college professor in Science, Technology and Society has much more schooling than an average attorney, but makes less money. Since he could have easily gone to law school, we can infer personal choice is a factor in his career decision. He likely prefers the intellectually stimulating environment of a university to the shark-eat-shark-eat-dolphin world of a private law office. Other factors that correlate with differences in income include: Region: In the United States, the median household income is highest in the Northeast, where the median annual household income is nearly $40,000. It is lowest in the South, at about $35,000. In most countries, incomes are far higher in urban areas than in rural areas; certain regions—such as Beijing and Shanghai in China—attract more investment and opportunities than others. Type of household: Married-couple families earn more than families headed by a single person. Type or nature of job: In every country, certain jobs will pay more. High school teachers will tend to earn more than textile workers, while bankers will tend to earn more than high school teachers. The Equal Pay Act of 1963 was intended to close the “wage gap” between men and women and between races in the United States. The gap is closing, but by less than a penny a year. Much of the ongoing difference may be due to factors that are hard to address—from differences in educational access and cultural preference, to gender-related lifestyle choices (for example, more women than men choose to leave the workforce to raise children, making them riskier investments for employers). Some of the difference is no doubt the legacy of discrimination at home and in the workplace. In many countries, women and certain ethnic groups face less favorable economic circumstances. Investment and Economic Growth As you have read, in order to improve labor productivity, we have to invest in human and physical capital. In fact, we invest in human and physical capital to improve the productivity of any resource. We ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 59 don’t just improve productivity for the sake of having more things. By investing in technology, physical capital, human capital, and the health of people, we raise our future standard of living. The standard of living is generally defined as the real value of the goods and services consumed by the average member of an economy. Take note: it’s not the average value of goods and services consumed; it’s the value of goods and services consumed by the average person in the economy. This turns out to be an important distinction—if income is concentrated in the top few percent, as it tends to be in developing countries, average income can be a misleading figure. Calculating standard of living can be difficult. Normally, we use Gross Domestic Product per capita to compare the standard of living from one country to the next. Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is something we’ll cover in macroeconomics; put simply, GDP is a measurement of national income. GDP per capita is national income per person. If GDP per capita increases over time, we can say economic growth is occurring, or that the standard of living has risen. In the very, very long-run, most economists believe economic growth can only result from technological advancements. Over shorter periods of time, investment in human and physical capital can also result in economic growth. When Destruction is a Good Thing Once upon a time, if you wanted to book a ticket from San Jose, California, to Newark, New Jersey, you had to visit your local travel agent. He or she would bring you a cup of coffee and find you a decent fare. Then the Internet came along. Entrepreneurs realized that people might want to book their own tickets online, comparing prices at home without changing out of their pajamas. They launched companies like Expedia and Travelocity. Before long, traditional travel agencies were running for their lives. This process by which entrepreneurs invent a new industry by destroying an old one is called creative destruction. The term, coined by the economist Joseph Schumpeter in the 1970s, is massively overused; every Internet entrepreneur wants you to believe that his or her idea is going to revolutionize an industry. But the truth is that some do. The rise of word processors obliterated typewriters. The emergence of Apple’s iPhone sent other mobile phone makers back to the drawing board----suddenly the flip phone looked as dated as VHS. First services such as NetFlix and now downloadable movies have wreaked havoc on the neighborhood movie rental business: it’s no coincidence Blockbuster went bankrupt. E-books-----led by the Kindle-----are tormenting traditional bookstores. Why is Barnes and Noble trying to sell its own e-reader, the Nook? Because it wants in on the new industry before the old one is gone. Creative destruction happens all the time; look for it in the products and services you choose to use from year to year. And, if you can figure out a way to creatively destroy something, you might end up very rich. Suppose you live on a small planet where everyone picks fruit from trees in order to eat. You are limited to eating the amount of fruit you can pick with your two hands. Suddenly a large spaceship lands nearby, carrying the entire population of a planet that suffered a nuclear war. The aliens are peaceful, but hungry. They are two-handed, just like you. And there are exactly as many of them inside the ship as there are people on your planet. Your planet’s population has just doubled. There is an immediate shortage of food, and the standard of living has just been reduced by half. In the short run, an investment in physical capital could restore the initial standard of living. In other words, someone needs to plant some more trees. Quickly. Skip ahead. The new trees have been planted. The population crisis has subsided. Everyone is living peacefully again now, eating exactly the same amount of fruit as before the spaceship landed. In the long run, there has been no change in the standard of living of the original residents. Now, the aliens come out with a product to make trees infinitely fruitful. No matter how much is picked, the trees never run out. This is an improvement in technology. Unfortunately, it is a useless ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 60 advance, because everyone still only has two hands. No one can pick any more than they could before, so no one can eat any more than they could before.50 At long last, a quiet little alien develops a potion that gives two more arms to everyone on the planet. Now there is endless fruit and twice as much picking power. People even invent fruit art. With the right investment in technology, the standard of living has improved in the long run. Entrepreneurs An entrepreneur combines the factors of production to make goods and services. Profit—of one kind or another—is the reward for entrepreneurship. But profit is never a sure thing. If it were, we’d all be entrepreneurs. The risk of entrepreneurship is that an entrepreneur will lose his investment. Consider Jason, an enterprising eight-year-old who mixes lemons, sugar, and water to make lemonade. He opens a lemonade stand on his street corner. If he can sell enough lemonade to recover the cost of his lemons, sugar, ice, and cups, then he’ll make a profit. But any number of things could go wrong, and Jason could lose his investment. If a storm rolls in one day, people might not be willing to buy Jason’s lemonade. He won’t collect enough revenue to cover his costs, so he’ll lose the money he spent buying his resources. If Katie, his adorable six-year-old sister, opens a stand next to Jason’s, people might choose her stand instead of his. Again, he won’t collect enough revenue to earn a profit.51 If Jason’s grandmother uses his lemons to make lemon bars, Jason will have to replace the lemons before he can even open up for the day—and he’ll have to sell enough lemonade to cover the cost of his usual resources and the replacement lemons. Jason can’t know what the weather will do. He can’t control his sister any more than he can control any other profit-hungry kid in the neighborhood. He certainly can’t control his grandmother. The risks of the lemonade business are vast, but Jason is an entrepreneur because he is willing to take them. Property rights can minimize the risks of entrepreneurship. When the police find Jason’s lemon bars in his grandmother’s kitchen, they can arrest her for possession of stolen property. There are ways to limit the risks of entrepreneurship. If there is an insurance company out there that insures lemonade stands, Jason can pay it a premium for protection against the loss he could suffer on a rainy day. Jason could buy insurance and never end up collecting a penny in benefits. But he could also buy insurance cheaply on a sunny day, and then it could rain for the next 14 days. Insurance mitigates risk, but at a cost that must be recouped. Well-enforced property rights can also help minimize the risks of entrepreneurship. Suppose Jason uses his own original recipe. As a business-savvy eight-year-old, he might have been smart enough to apply for a patent on it before he started doing business. That way, when Katie copied his recipe, he could have sued her. The court could have fined Katie and ordered her to pay Jason for his lost business.52 Similarly, when Jason came upon his empty fruit bowl, he could have filed a police report. Upon discovering the lemon bars in his grandmother’s kitchen, the police would have had probable cause to arrest his grandmother for possession of stolen property. The court could have ordered Jason’s grandmother to reimburse him, and to pay him for the damages his business suffered. 50 The squirrels are happy, though. Not until he hires an even cuter girl from down the street to man his stand. 52 Granted, Katie is only six. But years from now, Katie will probably thank her brother for teaching her a valuable lesson. 51 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 61 IV. Macroeconomics “We’re all Keynesians now,” American president Richard Nixon once said. Richard Nixon was a Republican, belonging to a political party traditionally opposed to Keynesian economic policies—yet even he had continued to implement and even expand them. Times have changed. We’re not all Keynesians anymore: Keynesian economics, in which the government adjusts taxes and spending to smooth out the business cycle, is just one approach to managing the economy. The main alternative, monetary policy, focuses on manipulating the money supply. This section will help you understand how the macroeconomy is measured and what kinds of issues shape these different policies. Gross Domestic Product and National Income Everyone in an economy, combined, produces a lot of stuff. It’s important to measure that stuff in order to gauge how the economy is doing—and in order to guide future economic policy. By definition, Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is that measure: it is the sum total of the market value of all final goods and services produced within an economy in a given period of time (usually yearly). Let’s take this definition apart. “Market value” is how much a good or service sells for. If people purchase a product for a given price, that is its market value. GDP is the total of the prices of final goods and services. “Final goods and services” are those ready to be sold to consumers. They are NOT goods headed to a factory to become part of another product. A new car is a final good, but the XM satellite radio receiver inside the car is not a final good. Only the sale price of the car is counted in GDP. This provision avoids double-counting. “…within an economy….” GDP only includes final goods and services that are physically produced within the borders of an economy. If an American manufacturer produces shoes in Taiwan, those shoes are not part of U.S. GDP. However, if a Taiwanese manufacturer produces shoes in the U.S., the shoes are included in U.S. GDP. “…a given period of time.” GDP is usually reported as an annual statistic, although it is tracked and calculated every quarter. In the press, you might read something like, “GDP increased this quarter at a slower rate than expected.” In economics textbooks, you’ll often see charts that track GDP from one year to the next. GDP per capita, mentioned in the last chapter, is the average output of an inhabitant in a country. It is determined by dividing a country’s GDP by its population. GDP per capita is often used to gauge the standard of living in a country. As with any simple average, however, GDP per capita does not reveal the equity of the distribution of income, so an impoverished country with a few wealthy people could appear to have a high standard of living if we only counted GDP per capita. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 62 Not long ago, the U.S. measured its output in terms of Gross National Product, or GNP. GNP is the sum total of the market value of all final goods and services produced by the citizens of a country during a given period of time. GNP is like GDP, except GNP counts the goods and services that are produced by the citizens of a particular nation, regardless of where. If a Chinese-owned firm is making spaghetti in Idaho, it counts toward the GDP of the United States.53 But, if an American-owned Starbucks sells lots of lattes in Shanghai, the sales do not count toward United States GDP. They count toward China’s GDP. Today, most economists use GDP, and not GNP, to measure the size of a country’s economy. In the United States, the Bureau of Economic Analysis is responsible for tabulating and reporting Gross Domestic Product. The Bureau reports on GDP every three months. Bear in mind that GDP is only a measure of the final value of goods and services. If GDP also included the value of raw or intermediate goods, it would overstate production. For example, if the value of the meat sold by a producer was counted in GDP, and later, if every DECADOG that contained the meat was also counted, then the meat would be double-counted. GDP would be overstated. No single statistic can tell the whole story Without a doubt, GDP is one of the most basic statistics in analyzing economies. Unfortunately, it is also one of the most widely misunderstood figures. GDP is an indicator of the size of an economy, but it is often quoted as an indicator of the health of an economy. The latter use is inaccurate. Politicians will sometimes mention ‘‘an increase in GDP’’ to suggest that they or their administration have improved life for everyone. But GDP is not a measure of economic well-being, nor was it ever intended to be one. For example, an increase in GDP could be the result of an increase in the production of gasguzzling vehicles, which emit more carbon dioxide than their fuel-efficient counterparts. Has our quality of life improved if we have larger, more comfortable cars? Or has it diminished if the air we breathe has more pollutants? There are two ways to avoid double counting. One is to count only final consumer goods and services (excluding raw and intermediate goods). Alternatively, GDP can be counted with a value-added method, in which a factor of production is followed through the production process, adding value to GDP each time it changes form, until it finally becomes a product. In the production of a milk chocolate bar, the value of the cacao is counted, then the value of the milk and sugar added to it. Later, the value of the chocolate wrapper is added, too, but nothing is included more than once. Some economists criticize GDP for not representing all the activity in an economy. For example, GDP does not include the value of used goods that are resold; these goods were counted the first time they were on the market. This means that auction sites such as eBay add basically nothing to GDP. Nor does GDP count the value of black market dealings54; in some countries, the underground economy is very significant. Household activities, such as washing your own clothes instead of sending them out to the dry cleaner, also go uncounted. Methods of GDP Measurement There are at least three ways of calculating GDP. In the income approach and the expenditures approach, GDP is determined as the sum of the market value of final goods and services. The outcome 53 It also counts toward the GNP of China. Demand and supply curves in black markets (as opposed to the corresponding curves in a legal market) can be affected by the additional costs of dodging law enforcement while buying and selling. 54 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 63 approach employs the value-added method. The outcome of each approach should be the same, though statistics being inexact, they rarely quite are. The Expenditures Approach to GDP Measurement The expenditures approach is the most frequently employed because it is the easiest to use. IT divides all economic transactions into four categories: Consumption, Investment, Government Spending and Net Exports. GDP is the sum of the categories. The expenditures approach is described by the equation Y = C + I + G + X. “Y” is GDP. In economic notation, “Y” always represents income. “C” represents Consumption, the transaction category that involves households buying goods and services from suppliers. Burgers, flights to China, laptops and haircuts are all examples of consumption. In the United States, consumption is the largest share of GDP. “I” represents Investment, including investments made by households and businesses, often through financial intermediaries. Investment creates value in the future. Often, investment is converted to capital, or man-made resources that produce more value. A firm’s purchase of a factory is an example of investment, as is a household’s purchase of an actual house. “G” represents Government spending. Government spends money on infrastructure, items such as roads, bridges and dams. It also spends on services, such as public education and national defense. The government can directly impact GDP by altering its fiscal policy. In theory, the “G” component of GDP can increase whenever the government chooses to increase it, because the government can borrow money to finance a budget deficit. “G” does not include transfer payments. A transfer payment is a “payment” made by the government to an individual for nothing in return. Welfare and social security are examples of transfer payments. They are excluded from GDP because they are not transactions: they only move money around, purchasing nothing. After receiving a transfer payment, a person will spend or invest it; at that point, the spending is counted in GDP. …“X” is Net Exports, or the difference between exports and imports. If there is a trade deficit (in which imports exceed exports), net exports will be negative. By Net Exports, we mean the value of all the exports a nation sells minus the value of all the imports it buys. An Americanmade television shipped to Paris adds to United States net exports because it was made in America. It is subtracted from France’s GDP because, to France, it is an import. Currently, X is very negative for the United States; we import much more than we export. The Income Approach to GDP Measurement National Income Accounting is a set of rules and definitions for measuring economic activity. It is paraphrased as the income approach, and it adds together all wages, salaries, corporate profits, interest payments, and rents. The income approach also subtracts indirect taxes and adds subsidies. Wages and salaries are what people are paid for their labor. Corporate profits are revenues to companies beyond the money they spend in production. Interest payments are the payments made to those who gave out loans. Rents are charges for borrowing other things of value, like an apartment or a car. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 64 An indirect tax is a government tax on a product, such as gasoline or tobacco. A subsidy is a government expenditure to lower the price of a good. Public television, state university tuition, and agricultural goods are often subsidized. GDP = Employee Compensation + Rents + Profits (- Indirect Taxes + Subsidies) + Interest Suppose employee compensation one year were $4 trillion, rents $2 trillion, corporate profits $1 trillion, and interest payments $3 trillion. Meanwhile, there were $1 trillion in indirect taxes and $1.5 trillion in subsidies. That year, GDP would have been $10.5 trillion. Calculating GDP with the Income Approach Employee Compensation $4 trillion + Rents $2 trillion + Corporate Profits $1 trillion + Interest Payments $3 trillion - Indirect Taxes $1 trillion + Subsidies $1.5 trillion GDP $10.5 trillion Other terms to remember are the net national product (NNP), national income (NI), personal income (PI), and disposable income (DI). Imagine a country generates $5 trillion in GDP using all its capital goods and a productively employed labor force. Unfortunately, some of the country’s capital deteriorates from year to year. For example, machinery in missile factories eventually breaks down. When you subtract the cost in any given year of replacing such depreciated capital from GNP, you are left with Net National Product. If you are starting with a country’s GDP, you need to adjust it to GNP first (by adding revenues by domestic interests abroad and removing revenues by foreign interests in the country). GNP minus depreciation = NNP National income is defined as the total amount of income paid for a country’s resources. It can be calculated by subtracting indirect taxes from NNP. NI = NNP minus indirect taxes Personal income is how much of this national income actually goes to individuals. It can be calculated by taking national income, then subtracting corporate profits that do not get distributed to stockholders, subtracting Social Security taxes, subtracting corporate taxes and subtracting payments on the national debt. PI = NI minus retained corporate earnings minus Social Security taxes minus corporate taxes minus national debt payments Disposable income is personal income minus income taxes but plus transfer payments (such as welfare and social security checks.) It is the actual portion of GDP people have left in their pockets to spend or save as they wish. DI = PI minus income taxes plus transfer payments Disposable income is the measurement most people “feel” on a day-to-day basis. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 65 The Output (Value-Added) Approach to GDP Measurement In the output approach, we gauge the value of everything produced in an economy by measuring the value added at each step in the production process. These can include goods, services, and anything else of value. The main problem with measuring GDP in this way is double counting. A car stereo is an example of a good that can overstate GDP because it is prone to double counting in the value-added method. Car manufacturers rarely produce their own stereos: they pay other firms to make stereos for them. Each stereo is sold twice: first, when its producer sells it to the car manufacturer and, later, when the dealer sells it—with a car attached. Each stereo is only created once, though, so it should not be included twice in GDP. To prevent counting the same production twice, we include only the value added by each transaction in a country’s GDP. Value added is defined as the difference between the sale price of a product, and the materials and processes used to create that product. To determine the value added by an automobile, economists determine the price paid by the dealer for every part that goes into the car. They then subtract that total from the selling price of the car. The difference is the car’s contribution to GDP. Real GDP and Nominal GDP We use the sale price of every good and service produced in an economy to determine Gross Domestic Product. If the price of a good increases because the quality of the good has improved, we would expect GDP to increase too: the economy is being more productive with the same amount of resources as it had used before. But if the price of a good increases due to inflation, GDP will increase even though the economy is no more productive than it was. Because of inflation, we need two different definitions of GDP: Nominal GDP is Gross Domestic Product expressed in terms of the current value of money. If the price of a good increases, nominal GDP will increase, too, regardless of whether the price increase is the result of improved quality. If nominal GDP increases from one year to the next, we have no way of knowing whether the economy was actually more productive in the second year. Real GDP is Gross Domestic Product with inflation factored out. When an economy is experiencing inflation, the prices of most goods and services will rise. If we eliminate inflation from nominal GDP for two consecutive years, then we can determine whether an economy was in fact more productive in the second year. If real GDP increased from one year to the next, then the economy really grew. Nominal GDP versus Real GDP Demilon’s GDP in Year 1 After Demilon is founded, the country produces 2 widgets in its first year. The widgets sell for three dollars each. There has been no inflation (since Demilon has only been around for a year), so nominal GDP and real GDP are both six dollars: The following year, Demilon’s widget makers arbitrarily raise their selling price to five dollars per widget and Demilon still produces only 2 widges. Nominal GDP increases to 10 dollars, even though Demilon is no more productive than it was the previous year. Real GDP does not increase, however. = $$$ = $$$ + Nominal GDP and Real GDP: $$$ $$$ ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 66 Demilon’s GDP after Inflation in Year 2 = $$$$$ = $$$$$ = $$$$$ = $$$$$ + Nominal GDP: + $$$ $$$ $$$ $ Real GDP: $$$ $$S Suppose the selling price of a widget did not change in Demilon in Year 2, and Demilon produced two more widgets, for a total of four. Both nominal GDP and real GDP increase to reflect the increase in productivity: Demilon’s GDP after an Increase in Productivity in Year 2 = $$$ $$$ = $$$ $$$ = $$$ $$$ = $$$ $$$ + Nominal GDP: + $$$ $$$ $$$ $$$ Real GDP: $$$ $$$ $$$ $$$ The Circular Flow of the Economy We can categorize economic activity as either productive or consumptive. Productive activity is what producers do; consumptive activity is what consumers do. To be more precise, we can say consumers consume what producers produce. Consumers get the cash for the goods from the producers themselves, in the form of wages and other payments made to them for resources such as land—in other words, employment income. This movement of goods, services, and money comprise the circular flow of the economy. To the right, the inner red arrow represents the money flow of the economy: households make payments to firms, and firms buy labor and other resources from households. The outer black arrow represents the real flow of the economy, or the movement of resources, goods, and services. In the resource market, firms obtain labor and other resources from households. The resource market is also called the factor market. In the goods and services market, households obtain goods and services from firms. In the circular flow model, money moves in the opposite direction of resources, goods, and services. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 67 Enter the Government No economy is as simple as the two-sector diagram. The model is incomplete if we ignore the government that is busy taxing both sectors while also buying their goods and services. In a mixed economy, most economic activity takes place in free markets, but the government has a role, too. When the government collects income taxes and sales taxes, money leaks from the circular flow. When the government buys goods and services from firms, money is injected into the circular flow. Money is also injected when the government transfers money directly to people as welfare payments or social security. These transfer payments do not involve the exchange of goods or services. Exports and Imports in the Circular Flow If an American firm produces a good and exports it, the firm receives money from abroad. The money is an injection into the money flow, and a leakage from the real flow. If a firm purchases a foreign good, the expenditure is a leakage from the money flow, but an injection to the real flow. Economic Growth You’ve probably heard politicians talk about wanting economic growth. They usually mean things like “more jobs” or “improved standards of living.” For economists, economic growth has a more precise definition. Economic growth is an increase in an economy’s ability to produce. Economic growth can be represented as an outward shift in the production possibilities frontier. It’s not an increase in production; it’s an increase in productive capacity. If an economy improves its technology, it will be able to produce more output for every combination of capital and consumer goods. Potential GDP increases, and the PPF shifts outward. Factors contributing to economic growth include, but are not limited to: Increase in capital Increase in resources Trade Improved human capital An increase in GDP does not necessarily mean that economic growth has occurred. Existing resources may just be coming into use. But if economic growth does occur, then GDP will most likely increase. For this reason, and just because it’s easier, when you hear people talk about economic growth, they are often talking about economic “downturns” and “upturns,” which are decreases and increases in business activity. Changes in GDP reflect these upturns and downturns. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 68 The Business Cycle Every so often you hear the economy is Debate it! slipping into a recession, but economists are usually calm about it55. They seem to Resolved: That governments should consider the economic benefits of going to war when choosing whether to become involved in a conflict. take for granted that the economy will recover and expand again. They are often more concerned with minimizing a recession’s impact and length than with asking, “How can we get rid of all recessions?” This is because the economy naturally moves back and forth between periods of expansion and contraction. This pattern is called the business cycle.56 Many American economics textbooks contain graphs depicting the country’s GDP, or the rate of growth of real GDP or GDP per capita, over the past century. Below is one such chart, based on data from the Department of Commerce. The points at which the change in real GDP is positive correspond to times of prosperity, and the points at which it is negative correspond to times of hardship. Wars tend to stimulate an economy; this Rate of Economic Growth in the United States occurs because in wartime the 20.0 government must spend a lot on the military. If “G” increases, then 15.0 “C+I+G+X” probably does, too. On the 10.0 graph, notice the growth around the times of World War II (early 1940s), the 5.0 Korean War (early 1950s), and the 0.0 Vietnam War (late 1960s-early 1970s). 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 -5.0 This does not mean wars are “good” for the economy. The extra spending keeps -10.0 industry and labor busy, but bombs and -15.0 planes do not directly provide utility to anyone other than the military. But the dollars spent making bombs and planes do flow to people and firms as wages and rent. Of course, if everyone is making missiles, this new money may not find enough new consumer goods to buy. This is why wars tend to coincide with inflation. On the chart you can also see the recent United States “tech boom” of the 1990s, represented by a steady positive growth rate, and, further back, the recessions of the early 1990s and late 1970s. The most significant recession in the past century was the Great Depression, a period of hardship from the late 1920s into the 1930s. The data only reaches back to 1930, but you can see how the curve begins deep in the negative. In the United States, the Great Depression followed a period of prosperity in the 1920s (often referred to as the Roaring Twenties). When the economy is booming, people are quick to believe things will be good forever. In the 1990s, books with titles like Dow 30,000 predicted the stock market would rise forever. Caught up in the bandwagon—what Federal Reserve chairman Alan Greenspan labeled 55 56 Except in 2008, when the economy slipped off a cliff. The business cycle follows no specific pattern. It’s hard to predict expansions and depressions. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 69 “irrational exuberance”—many did not safeguard against the inevitable downturn when the “dotcom boom” came to an end around 2000. The stock market spent much of the next decade lurching up and down without going decisively in either direction—a classic “bear” market. Home values soared, however57—as did consumer debt—creating another unsustainably exuberant state of affairs. It came to a crashing halt in September 2008, when the United States suffered its greatest stock market decline since 911. The final section of this resource details this crash and its causes and consequences. The historical business cycle can be charted through changes in real GDP, in the rate of economic growth, or, less often, in the unemployment rate. Any analysis of the business cycle reveals a number of different points and periods. Expansion occurs when business activity grows for at least two quarters (six months). A peak occurs at the end of an expansion. It is the high point of the business cycle. After a peak, business activity decreases. The start of this fall is an economic downturn. By definition, a recession occurs when real GDP (i.e. domestic economic activity) decreases for two consecutive quarters. A depression is a severe recession. There is no actual textbook definition for the point at which a recession becomes so severe that it can be called a depression. A trough occurs at the end of a recession. It is the lowest point in the business cycle. When a trough ends, a new economic upturn begins. Business activity begins to increase again, and the economy enters a fresh period of expansion. Economic Indicators Leading indicators hint at where the business cycle is heading in the future. They measure things like how many buildings are scheduled for construction (more is better) and how consumers are feeling about the future. In the United States, they include: Average workweek of manufacturing workers Unemployment insurance claims New orders for consumer goods and materials, adjusted for inflation Vendor performance (how quickly are orders being filled?) New orders for capital goods New building permits issued Index of stock prices 57 Many people used money they had earned in stock boom of the 1990s to buy real estate, driving prices upward. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 70 Changes in the money supply (M2) Difference between the 10-year Treasury bond rate and the Federal funds rate Index of consumer expectations Coincident economic indicators give a sense of the current economic situation. They tell us what things are like now. They include: Manufacturing and trade sales Level of non-agricultural unemployment Level of industrial production Average personal income (minus transfer payments) Lagging indicators measure past economic conditions, usually from the last few months. They include: Mean prime interest rate Average span of unemployment Ratio of inventories to sales Changes in labor cost per unit of output Number and size of commercial and industrial loans Ratio of consumer debt to income Change in consumer price index for services Aggregate Demand Aggregate demand is the demand for all domestic output at each possible price level. It is the sum of the demand for all goods and services produced domestically. Earlier we saw how, when the price of a good or service increases, people are willing and able to buy less of it, so the quantity demanded decreases. Aggregate demand works the same way. When the price level is high—when everything seems more expensive than it used to be—people will be willing and able to buy fewer goods and services. One way of thinking about the aggregate demand curve is as the result of adding the demand curve for every good and service produced within an economy. It is similar to the demand curve for an individual good. The major difference is in the axes. The vertical y-axis on the graph for a single good has actual numeric prices, like $5 or $10. But a single price would not make sense on the aggregate graph. Instead, the y-axis is of the overall price level for an economy. The actual price level does not matter, just whether it increases or decreases. If goods and services increase in price (inflation), the price level will go up. The “price level” can refer to a specific industry, or to a specific sector of an economy, or to the whole economy. The horizontal x-axis is the quantity demanded of an economy’s total output. In the expenditures approach, we find GDP by adding up how much society spends. The equation for this method is Y = C + I + G + X. If there is a change in consumption, investment, government spending, or net exports, there must be a change in aggregate demand, too. The aggregate demand curve has a negative slope for two reasons. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 71 First: as the price level decreases, goods become cheaper; in effect, consumers have more wealth, so are willing to consume more real output. This is the wealth effect of changes in the price level. Second: as the price level falls, domestic goods grow cheaper for consumers abroad. Exports increase and imports decrease. This is the international, or exchange-rate, effect of changes in the price level. Just as the demand curve for a single good can shift right or left, so can the aggregate demand curve. To understand how the aggregate demand curve is affected by economic events, let’s revisit the expenditures approach to GDP calculation. In it, we find GDP by adding up how much is spent in an economy—that is, we look at the demand side of GDP. The equation for this approach is Y = C + I + G + X. If consumption, investment, government spending, or net exports change, then you can expect aggregate demand will, too, because those are the components of what is spent on aggregate output. 1. This brings us to the first factor affecting aggregate demand: a change in foreign income. Aggregate demand is the total demand for U.S. goods—and, if foreign income falls, there will be less of a demand for U.S. exports from buyers abroad. Net exports will decrease. In the equation Y = C + I + G + X, a decrease in net exports is a decrease in “X.” On the other side of the equation, “Y” must decrease, too; aggregate demand decreases and the aggregate demand curve shifts to the left. A Change in Foreign Income Y = C + I + G + X Y = C + I + G + X Price Level A decrease in foreign income lowers the demand for exports, resulting in a decrease in aggregate demand. The aggregate demand curve shifts to the left. AD2 AD1 Quantity of Output Demanded 2. If firms’ expectations of future income increase, they’ll be willing to invest in the present. “I” increases so “Y” increases. Aggregate demand shifts to the right. If consumers have positive expectations about their future incomes, they’ll be willing to buy more at each price level in the present. The aggregate demand curve will shift to the right. Positive expectations about future income convince firms and private individuals to invest. The increase in investment results in an increase in aggregate demand. The aggregate demand curve shifts to the right. Y = C + I + G + X Price Level A Change in Expectations about Future Income AD1 Y = C + I + G + X Quantity of Output Demanded AD2 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 72 3. If firms’ and consumers’ expectations of future prices rise (that is, if they expect inflation will occur in the future) then they will want to buy more in the present, while the price level is lower. When consumers buy more, there is an increase in consumption, or “C” in the expenditures equation, so there must be an equal increase in “Y.” The aggregate demand curve will shift to the right. A Change in the Expected Future Price Level Y = C + I + G + Price Level The expectation of inflation motivates consumers to buy more output in the present. The increase in consumption results in an increase in aggregate demand. The aggregate demand curve shifts to the right. X AD1 AD2 Quantity of Output Demanded 4. Exchange rates also affect aggregate demand. If the dollar loses value (depreciates) relative to other currencies, domestic consumers will be less able to buy foreign goods. Foreigners will be more able to buy suddenly “cheaper” American goods. Thus, when the dollar weakens, net exports increase. An increase in “X” leads to an increase in “Y.” The aggregate demand curve shifts to the right. An increase in the exchange rate makes U.S. goods cheaper to foreigners, so the demand for net exports increases. The increase in ‘‘X’’ results in an increase in aggregate demand, so the curve shifts to the right. Y = C + I + G + X Price Level A Change in the Exchange Rate AD1 AD2 Quantity of Output Demanded 5. The distribution of income has an effect on aggregate demand. If distribution changes so lowerincome families receive a larger share of national income, aggregate demand will increase—because lower-income families spend a more of their income on consumption than do higher-income families. When “C” increases, “Y” increases, so the aggregate demand curve will shift to the right. The Effect of Income Distribution The redistribution of income puts more money in the hands of the poor-----who spend more money on consumer goods than the wealthy do. The increase in consumption results in an increase in aggregate demand, so the curve shifts to the right. Y = C + I + G + Price Level ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 73 X AD1 AD2 Quantity of Output Demanded 6. Many government policies aim to shift the aggregate demand curve. If the government runs a deficit, it must be spending that money somewhere. If government spending (“G”) increases, “Y” must increase, too. The aggregate demand curve shifts to the right. When the government runs a deficit, it does so to stimulate the economy by spending money, and ultimately putting it in the hands of consumers who spend it again. The increase in government spending results in an increase in aggregate demand. The aggregate demand curve shifts to the right. Y = C + I + G + X Price Level A Change in Government Spending AD1 AD2 Quantity of Output Demanded Consumption and the Marginal Propensity to Consume Suppose you were as a teacher earning a salary of $50,000. Of this, you might spend $40,000 on consumption—paying for your house, your meals, your photocopies and your car—and you might save $10,000 for the future. Now suppose you received a raise to a yearly salary of $60,000. Will you spend all $10,000 of new income on consumption goods? No. Will you put it all in the bank? No. You’ll probably spend some of it and save the rest. The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) refers to this phenomenon. People tend to consume a certain percentage of new earnings and to save the remaining sum for future needs. If the MPC in an economy is 0.8, then 80% of each additional dollar will be consumed and 20% saved. If the MPC is 0.9, then 90% of each additional dollar will be consumed and 10% saved. The marginal propensity to save (MPS) is the flip-side of the marginal propensity to consume. If the MPS is 0.15, then 15% of each additional dollar earned will be saved and 85% consumed. Together, the MPS and MPC always equal 1. Displayed is a diagram that plots the amount of money consumers in the United States use on consumption against their total disposable income. It is called a consumption function. Connecting all of these points shows that the data forms a nearly perfect straight line. REAL CONSUMER SPENDING (IN TRILLIONS OF 1982 DOLLARS) ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 74 REAL DISPOSABLE U.S. INCOME THROUGH 1985 (IN TRILLIONS OF 1982 DOLLARS) When points form a straight line, they imply a definite relationship between the two variables. Here, consumption on the vertical axis is almost always about 90% of disposable income. The data point for 1960 represents an income of about $1.1 trillion for all consumers and consumption of about $1.0 trillion. The point for 1985 represents $2.63 trillion in income and $2.35 trillion in consumption. Each year, in other words, Americans consistently spent 90% of their incomes on goods and services; the line thus has a slope of 0.9. Keynes argued that the MPC remains fairly constant for a nation through time. Despite recessions, depressions, economic recoveries, or alien invasion, consumers continue to spend about the same fraction of their incomes on themselves. The data above indicates he was right. For decades, U.S. consumers have continued to spend about 90% of their disposable incomes on consumption. The Multiplier Effect Suppose an elderly woman had $20,000 under her mattress, which she finally decided to spend on her eightieth birthday. Her society has a MPC of 0.8, meaning 80% of each dollar earned in disposable income is spent on consumption. 1 Multiplier = 1 MPC A Total Increase = 1 MPC When she spends her $20,000, the people who receive that sum— travel agents, car salesmen, telemarketers, whoever—will in turn A = initial amount spent spend 80% of it, or $16,000. The new holders of the $16,000 will MPC = marginal propensity to consume also spend 80% of it, or $12,800, on their own chosen goods—gel for their hair, cologne, anything at all. By now you follow the gist of this: the recipients of the $12,800 will spend 80% of it, or $10,240, and this in turn will be spent in the same ratio, on and on, until the money is exhausted. What matters most is the overall result. If you have a mathematical background in sequences and series, you may recognize that we are looking at the sum of an infinite series with a factor of 0.8. The formula for finding this sum is shown above. The multiplier gives us a good sense of how many times each dollar will be spent. It can be found by dividing the marginal propensity to save into 1, or (1-MPC) into 1, as shown to the right. In a society ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 75 with an MPC of 0.8, the multiplier is 5; if the MPC were .5, the multiplier would be only 2. The lower the MPC, the less often money will be spent. To find the total spending that the injection of a particular amount of money into the economy will cause, we multiply that amount by the multiplier. If someone spends $15,000 in an economy with an MPC of 0.8, it will then be spent 5 times—resulting in a final spending increase of $75,000. ‘‘Ideal’’ vs. ‘‘Real’’ Multipliers What we have just calculated above is called the “ideal multiplier,” or the “oversimplified multiplier.” Why the extra label? Because often a theory can be nice, but experimental evidence shows something else. In real life, the multiplier is not as high as the calculated “ideal” multiplier. The reasons for this: inflation tends to decrease the purchasing power of this new money to spend some of the extra money is spent on imported goods (and, therefore, goes abroad) taxes and other expenses take a portion of the money out of circulation each time it is spent. Again, the MPC for the United States is close to 0.9—maybe a bit lower since the crash of 2008. This gives us an ideal multiplier of around 10. Various studies have tended to show that for the United States the real multiplier amounts only to about 2. Analysts admit there is no very accurate way to measure the multiplier, since so many forces and confounding variables are involved. Aggregate Supply and Economic Equilibrium Aggregate supply is the quantity of domestic output suppliers are willing to produce and sell at every possible price level. It is the sum of the supply of every good or service produced in an economy. Remember, as the price of a good or service increases, the quantity supplied of the good or service increases, too. The aggregate supply works roughly the same way. As the price level rises, suppliers are willing to produce and sell more of their goods and services. Aggregate supply differs from the supply of a single good. Generally, more of a single good or service can be produced by allocating resources from the production of other goods and services. But this is not possible in the aggregate because there is ultimately a limited supply of resources. Consider a comparison. Suppose you wanted to enlarge a room in your house. We could expand any one room by borrowing space from other rooms or from the yard. But we couldn’t expand the whole house beyond the plot of land we own.58 When suppliers are producing at full capacity, the aggregate supply curve becomes completely price-inelastic. Regardless of what consumers are willing to pay, we have reached the maximum capacity of the economy (the edge of the production possibility frontier). Below full capacity, the supply curve has a positive slope. 58 Assume we can’t build a second floor. There’s a floor ceiling. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 76 In the long run, the supply curve is believed to be vertical. Someday, oil producers won’t be able to offer more oil because there won’t be more to offer—no matter how much consumers are willing to pay. Where the aggregate supply curve becomes vertical, the economy is at full employment; suppliers are using all the resources available to them. In other words, the economy is producing at a point on its production possibilities frontier. At any point below full employment, suppliers would be producing below capacity, at a point within the PPF. A shift to the left or right of the aggregate supply curve results from a change in potential output. The same factors that shift the PPF, including the availability of resources, size of the labor force, capital, entrepreneurship and technology, will cause changes in aggregate supply. When the economy is in full employment equilibrium, the aggregate demand curve intersects the aggregate supply curve exactly at full employment. If the economy is in recession equilibrium, the aggregate demand curve will intersect the aggregate supply curve at a point below full employment. The economy will be at a point inside its production possibilities frontier because suppliers will not be using all the resources they have available to them. The Labor Force The labor force includes every civilian Debate it! over age 16 who either has a job— full-time or part-time—or who is Resolved: That people of all ages, including children, should be allowed to participate in the labor force. actively seeking a job. We must be very precise with this definition, so, here, we will explore the standard United There is no such States interpretation of it. Let’s break it down, bearing in mind that the details thing as an of the definition do vary between countries. “…civilian…” Those who serve in the military are not counted in the labor force. Civilians who work for the military, like a custodian at the Pentagon, are not considered military personnel. unemployed 14year-old. “…over age 16…” Even if you have a job, you are not counted as part of the labor force until you are 16. You can’t technically be unemployed if you’re not in the labor force. This means there is no such thing as an unemployed 14-year-old, even if he or she is looking for a job. “…has a job…” A person who has a job—and is over 16, of course—is part of the labor force. “…full-time or part-time…” The CEO of Facebook and the head fry cook at McDonald’s are both part of the labor force, even if the cook works 60 hours per week and the CEO only 25. “…actively seeking a job…” Even if a person has no job, he or she is part of the labor force as long as he or she wants one and is looking for one. But take note: you are only “actively” job-seeking if you are turning in applications and scheduling and attending interviews. If your slacker friend sits around ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 77 playing WoW while mumbling about how he’d like to have a job, he isn’t part of the labor force. Tobe counted, he has to be off that couch, polishing his shoes, and shaking hands with middle managers. The Labor Force Participation rate (LFP rate)59) is the percentage of the civilian population in the labor force out of all the people who could be in it. In other words, it is the percentage of noninstitutionalized people over age 16 who are working or seeking work. Anyone over 16 who doesn’t want to work, like a housewife or a full-time student, lowers the LFP rate. It is found as follows: Labor Force = Participation rate # of people in the labor force # of people over 16 in the civilian population x 100 In the United States, the Bureau of Labor Statistics is responsible for tabulating how many people have jobs, how many want jobs, how many have jobs they want, etc. Every month, it conducts a household survey to determine the current unemployment rate. According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, the labor force consists of people who are employed and people who are unemployed. A person who is employed is one who has a job, either full-time or parttime. A person who is unemployed is in the labor force but does not have a job. To reiterate, someone who chooses to not work is not considered unemployed even though he is not working—he is not part of the labor force. Labor Force = Employed + Unemployed The employment rate is the percentage of the labor force that is employed: number of people who are employed number of people who are in the labor force Employment rate = x 100 The unemployment rate is the percentage of the labor force that is unemployed: number of people who are unemployed number of people who are in the labor force Unemployment rate = x 100 A person in the labor force is either employed or unemployed. There is nothing in between. So the employment rate plus the unemployment rate should always total 100 percent. Unemployment Rate + Employment Rate = 100 % Categories of Unemployed Persons Some people just lose their jobs. The Bureau of Labor Statistics calls these people “job-losers” (really). Some job-losers are temporarily laid off, or furloughed, perhaps for a month or less. Some are laid off for good. Some are strongly encouraged to resign or retire. And, of course, some people are fired. What all job-losers have in common is that they leave their jobs against their will. 59 The United States Labor Force Participation rate hovers between 65 and 67 percent. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 78 Job-leavers voluntarily leave their jobs. Some move on to better jobs right away, so are not part of the unemployment problem. Others may leave a job without knowing what to do next—perhaps because they are unhappy, sexually harassed, or facing pressure from their spouses. New entrants are unemployed because they joined the labor force. They have never had jobs, so they need to find employers who will hire them without experience. Re-entrants left the labor force and are now returning to it. While out of the labor force, they are not considered unemployed. But once they begin seeking jobs, they rejoin the labor force and drive up the unemployment rate. Some people leave to raise children, to spend time with their families, or to travel through rural Morocco. When they come back, they typically look for jobs similar to those they had before they stopped working. Some leave the labor force to go to school. When they return, they often want jobs in which they can employ their new training. They may or may not find them. Kinds of Unemployment Economists define four kinds of unemployment. Frictional unemployment occurs when people are Debate it! between jobs for “normal” reasons. In the ordinary Resolved: That the government should not help course of business, people quit and are fired. Because frictional unemployment is unavoidable, economists unemployed people who quit their jobs voluntarily. tend not to worry much about it. Frictional unemployment is a large part of the reason the unemployment rate is never 0%. Most economists think a rate of about 4% is normal and inevitable. Structural unemployment happens when there are changes in demand for certain skills in an economy, often due to technological change—for example, suppose postal workers were laid off because everyone stopped sending real mail in favor of email. Structural unemployment is also often caused by realignment of economic activities, such as the shift of manufacturing jobs from developed to developing nations. Unlike those who are frictionally unemployed, those who are structurally unemployed have a serious problem. They must often either take jobs with lower pay or switch into a different field, perhaps after some retraining. Cyclical unemployment results from fluctuations in the business cycle. The workers who are laid off because of a recession are cyclically unemployed. Their skills are not obsolete, so most of them will probably be working again when the economy recovers. The Employment Act of 1946 was aimed at alleviating cyclical unemployment. Until it expired in 2000, it made the government responsible for minimizing the volatility of the business cycle and for pursuing four percent unemployment. Seasonal unemployment is the result of changes in the season during the year. Most ski instructors lose employment in the summer, while swim teachers are out of jobs in the winter (except in places like Hawaii and Cancun). Many agricultural jobs are also seasonal. Since we can’t do much to stop the seasons from changing, we need to help employees to diversify their skills. If a ski instructor learns how to teach swimming and rake leaves, he or she ought to have a job year-round. Four Portraits of Unemployment Mike leaves his job at K-Mart so he can move to a new home in another city. Once there, he begins applying for positions at other discounters. Mike is unemployed. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 79 Megan is a conductor of the pit orchestras that accompany operas on Broadway. Suddenly all Broadway theaters decide to use the Internet to replace live human conductors with less expensive conductors from abroad. Megan is unemployed. Kim works in the furniture relocation industry. When a recession sets in, a quarter of the industry is laid off, Kim included. She has to bide her time looking for work until another contractor finds value in her services. Like Mike and Megan, Kim is unemployed. Montgomery is a high school student who finds work at a pumpkin stand in October. In November, Montgomery is laid off because no one is buying pumpkins. Mike, Megan, Kim and Montgomery each typifies a different kind of unemployment. Mike is frictionally unemployed. Friction is the force between two objects that are touching; we might think of Mike as sandwiched between two jobs, the one he had the one he is looking for. Megan is structurally unemployed. There has been a major shift in the economy, resulting in her replacement by someone ten thousand miles away. Structural unemployment stems from changes in what or how an economy produces. Kim is cyclically unemployed. Her job depends on the condition of the economy. During recessions and depressions, many workers are laid off. During a recovery, they are (hopefully) rehired. As for Montgomery, he is seasonally unemployed. His employer is likely to rehire him the following October, when pumpkins are in demand again. But for the moment, he’s not needed. Money and Currency Barter economies are inefficient. Remember from earlier in this resource that in order to barter people must have a double coincidence of wants. This reduces the number of possible transactions. To trade without bartering, an economy must have some form of money. We are all familiar with money because we are all used to having it. But take a step back and consider what a strange thing money is. In the United States, it comes in the form of pieces of mostly green paper with pictures of dead presidents on them.60 In China, the colors are different and the pictures are all of Mao Zedong. Everywhere, people sacrifice hours of their time in return for the promise of these pieces of paper. But people won’t work for just any piece of paper—except maybe for certificates of achievement in the World Scholar’s Cup. What is so special about United States dollars and other forms of currency that makes people willing to work so hard for them? The main answer should be pretty straightforward. Dollars let us buy goods and services. World Scholar’s Cup certificates do not.61 Currency includes only paper money and coins, but check are written to represent some amount of currency held elsewhere. Checks allow the pieces of paper to be shuffled offstage. 60 61 Except for Ben Franklin. He’s the only exception. Don’t try it. You can’t even exchange them for alpacas. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 80 There are two main kinds of money. Fiat money is money with no inherent value—it is money only because the government declares it to be money and people believe the government. It has no real value outside of being money. There aren’t many other things you could do with dollar bills. You could line a bird cage with them, but a newspaper would work better. You could take notes on dollar bills, but they’re hard to read: a pad of lined paper would probably be better. They also make very uncomfortable toilet paper.62 For the most part, dollar bills are only useful if you’re spending them. Unlike fiat money, commodity money has value besides its use as money. If chocolate were money, you could choose to spend it or to eat it. If cigarettes were money, you could spend them or smoke them. Both chocolates and cigarettes have often been used as money in prisons. Gold and silver are good examples of more widely-used commodity money. They are both precious metals with market value, as we all know from commercials urging us to invest in them, and the raw ingredients of jewelry and other goods. Most currencies were historically made from precious metals—which led people to try and fake the metals, or to mix them with less valuable metals without anyone noticing. The term ‘commodity’ in commodity money refers to the fact that anything used for money must be widely available, standardized, and easy to value on the market. If it is not a commodity but a more unique good, such as handmade hats, then we are partly back to the original problem of bartering. The Three Functions of Money Money acts as a medium of exchange, which is why money is more efficient than a barter system. If you can exchange money for the things you need, then you need only to exchange the things you have (such as your time and effort) for money. Then you can exchange your money for the things you want. Everyone must still provide goods and services that are wanted, but they can be goods and services that are not necessarily wanted by the people with products that you want. Money acts as a unit of account. It measures the relative worth of different goods and services and the relative wealth of different people, organizations and nations. If you spend $5 on a Happy Meal in San Francisco, you know you’re giving up a $5 e-book or half a $10 t-shirt. It is harder to gauge value in a barter system, because all products and services are worth different amounts to different people. MediumofExchange • Youcanusemoneytobuy productsfrompeoplewho mightnotwanttobarter withyouforyourused socks,butarehappytotake yourusedcash. UnitofAccount • Youcanmeasurethecostof things‐‐likeheadphones, Facebook,andCramKits‐‐in termsofthemoneyitwould taketobuythem. StoreofValue • Ifitisworth$50today,it willbeworth$50nextyear. Money also acts as a store of value. You can spend a fifty dollar bill, and in return, you’ll get a fire extinguisher. However, you could also hang on to it. You could keep it in your pockets, under your mattress or in your bank account. After a few weeks, you could still pick up a Happy Meal—several, in fact. Money retains value. If yogurt were money, you would have to spend it before it went bad.63 62 63 Trust me on this. Or, you could feed it to Michael Weston. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 81 Types of Money and the Money Supply The money supply is the total money in an economy. Currency—actual cash and coins—is only a small part of this total. For every U.S. citizen, there are only about $1,500 of currency in circulation. Economists measure the money supply in different ways. Each differs in the liquidity of the money it counts, or how easily it can be converted to something you can spend at a store. If it takes a pawnshop to convert something to cash, it isn’t very liquid—but it’s still more liquid than, say, your arm. M1 is the most liquid definition of the money supply. It consists of currency, demand deposits (such as your checking account) and travelers’ checks.64 M2 is less liquid than M1, but is still liquid enough that many economists consider it the most accurate measure of the money supply. All of M1 is included in M2, as are savings accounts, certificates of deposit65 (CDs) under $100,000, and money market and mutual fund (“retail money”) shares. M3 takes M2 and adds large time deposits, such as CDs worth more than $100,000, along with Eurodollars (American dollars held in banks abroad) and money market funds that take a very long time to return money to investors. The United States Federal Reserve stopped measuring M3 in 2006. Definitions of the Money Supply L. L stands for “liquid” and is not a standard measure. It includes M3 and some loans, such as treasury bonds and commercial paper (loans to companies.) When economists talk about the money supply, they are usually referring to M2. Inflation and Price Indices U.S. Money Supply Since 1960 By the time we reach high school, we have probably witnessed some inflation firsthand. Prices for most goods and services go up over time. In 1962, when the first Motel 6 opened in Santa Barbara, it charged $6 a night per room—that’s why they called it Motel 6! By the 1980s, it charged over $40 a night. Today that same room will run you $99.66 When inflation is taking place, all prices are going up—and so, in theory, are wages and rents. You might wonder, then, why inflation is such a big deal. If everything costs more, and everyone is being paid more—nothing is really changing. 64 Traveler’s checks are falling out into disuse as more and more travelers carry credit cards—but your parents may have used them when they went on European vacations after high school. 65 A CD is a time deposit: when you buy one, you deposit a certain amount in a bank and agree not to withdraw it for a period of time. At the end, you get back your deposit, plus interest. The longer the period, the higher the interest rate. 66 But it comes with free wifi! ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 82 It is true that inflation does not directly affect economic activity. If all prices are going up, producers continue to produce the same number of products—just at the new nominal price. Economists credit this behavior to what they call price neutrality: markets, in other words, care only about real prices. They are “neutral” with regard to nominal prices. However, inflation does have an effect on both firms and households. Inflation is good news for borrowers with a fixed interest loan. Suppose someone has borrowed $5,000 and promised to pay back 5% a year. If inflation is suddenly 10% a year, the value of what they owe is actually shrinking over time. The lender is in the opposite situation—he or she loses out. U.S. Money Supply in October 2010 M1 Currency: $907.6 Traveler’s Checks: $4.8 Demand Deposits: $480.3 Other Checkable Deposits: $386.9 TOTAL: $1,779.6 M2 M1: $1779.6 Savings Deposits: $5298.4 Small Denomination Time deposits: $967.8 Retail Money Funds: $721.3 TOTAL: $8,767.1 Societies pursue price stability because inflation has some substantial economic costs: Inflation lowers the buying power of people living on fixed incomes, such as retirees and welfare recipients. Some forms of fixed income do adjust for inflation over time, but not all at once. People may find their savings are suddenly worth much less, especially if they were holding them in cash, not in hard assets, such as gold, whose prices rise with inflation. The shoe leather cost of inflation is a metaphorical term for the costs of making frequent trips to the bank to withdraw more cash. This metaphor is less relevant now, as lots of people bank online67 and use credit cards. Financial markets cannot handle unpredictable inflation. Banks have trouble valuing loans when it is unclear what they will be worth over time. Erratic inflation rates can lead to diminished investment activity, which directly impacts economic growth. Another cost of inflation is the menu cost—because, in theory, restaurants have to keep printing new menus to keep up with inflation. Some firms, such as gas stations, can easily adjust prices every day, but others are not so flexible. If inflation is high or unpredictable, firms have no choice but to change prices constantly.68 Related to menu costs is the allocative cost. The relative prices of goods do not always adjust at the same rate. Say oranges normally cost twice as much as memory sticks—but, while 67 Now it could be called carpal tunnel cost. Some firms have long-term contracts with fixed prices. If inflation is higher or lower than expected, one party loses and one gains. For a long time, Southwest Airlines was able to stay profitable despite rising oil prices because it had signed a longterm contract for fuel at lower prices. 68 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 83 orange farmers can raise prices quickly in an inflationary period, memory stick makers cannot. They are locked in by published catalogue prices, etc. For a time, oranges will cost three times as much as memory sticks. Consumers will favor memory sticks, which is difficult on the orange growers.69 Goods will be allocated inefficiently. The planning cost of inflation refers to the fact that it takes a lot more time to plan budgets and think about future earnings if there is high or unpredictable inflation. Even for those whose wages adjust to inflation, there is still a cost called the hidden tax: Progressive tax brackets are usually defined nominally and not adjusted to inflation very often. Thus, inflation pushes people into higher tax brackets for the same real income. Demand-pull inflation occurs when aggregate demand increases, but supply is maxed out—at least in the short run. When aggregate demand intersects aggregate supply at the full employment level of output, any further increase in demand will push up the price level without producing more output. We can summarize demand-pull inflation as too many dollars chasing too few goods. To stop it, we must reduce aggregate demand. Cost-push inflation occurs when the price of goods and services increases because the prices of inputs—such as oil—increase. Firms have to pay more to produce, so aggregate supply shifts to the left. The equilibrium price level rises even though no more output is exchanged. Cost-Push Inflation Structural inflation is less common, caused by a shift in demand from one type of good to another. For example, many companies have moved from glass to plastic containers.70 The change pushes the demand curve for plastic outward, raising its price. You might think the lower demand for glass would reduce proportionally, but not necessarily. Prices increase far more easily than they decrease; economists say prices are sticky in the downward direction. This is not always true, of course, especially with high-tech products like hard drives, which tend to decline in price as production technology improves—though manufacturers can keep prices on others high by releasing shiny new models. To measure inflation, we must observe and measure any movement in the price level. From one quarter to the next, prices may shift upward or downward. The Consumer Price Index (CPI) is the standard tool for measuring inflation in the United States. The Bureau of Labor Statistics calculates the Consumer Price Index. Each month, it measures what it costs to purchase a fixed “market basket” of consumer goods and services. The market basket includes goods that Americans buy frequently.71 The market basket does not include luxury items or financial 69 And might lead to scurvy, unless the memory sticks are vitamin-c-enhanced. Examples include Voss water and Pom pomegranate juice (which I nearly called pomeranian juice.) 71 Thus, it includes breakfast cereal, but not congee. 70 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 84 instruments such as stocks and bonds. The CPI uses a fixed basket of goods so it can consistently measure changing prices. However, this is also its weakness, as increasing prices of goods in the market basket may drive consumers to lower-priced substitutes. What goods and services does the CPI cover? Food and Beverages Housing Apparel Transportation Medical Care Recreation Education and Communication Other Goods And Services breakfast cereal, milk, coffee, chicken, wine, service meals and snacks rent of primary residence, owners’ equivalent rent, fuel oil, bedroom furniture men’s shirts and sweaters, women's dresses, jewelry new vehicles, airline fares, gasoline, motor vehicle insurance prescription drugs and medical supplies, doctors’ services, hospital services televisions, pets and pet products, sports equipment, admissions college tuition, postage, telephone services, software and PC accessories tobacco and smoking products, haircuts and personal services, funeral expenses The CPI is expressed as a percentage of a given earlier year. The earlier year is called the base year. For example, if the CPI for a particular year is 163, then the price level that year is 63 percent higher than it was in the base year. For simplicity, the base year is kept the same for several years at a time. That way, we can more easily understand the movement of the price level. Inflation is expressed as the percentage by which the current price level exceeds the prior price level. This inflation rate is determined as follows: price levelyear - price levelprevious year price levelprevious year Inflation rateyear = x 100 Suppose for 1998 the price index is 163.0 and for 1997 it is 160.5. The inflation rate for 1998 is: Inflation rate1998 Inflation rate1998 = price index1998 - price index1997 price index1997 x 100% = 163.0 - 160.5 160.5 x 100% = 2.5 160.5 x 100% = 1.6% Economists use the CPI to measure inflation because the demand for consumer goods represents the bulk of aggregate demand. If consumer prices are rising, we can assume other prices are rising, too. Although price levels usually increase, they can Watch it on YouTube also decrease. This is called deflation. History’s most notorious period of hyperinflation occurred in Deflation is rare, in part because prices are Germany in the 1920s. Watch this clip for a sense of what this sticky in the upward direction: it is harder to experience was like for the German people: convince stores to raise prices than to lower http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=MCU6Fcnc2H0 them. The most pronounced period of deflation in American history occurred from 1928 to 1933, at the onset of the Great Depression—when ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 85 numerous banks shut down and people’s savings vanished, leaving less money in circulation. At a very basic level, less money meant the remaining money was worth more. Economists use a few other specialized terms to describe inflationary developments: Hyperinflation means inflation is very high—for instance, 50% per month. When countries go through hyperinflation, their governments tend to break down. Disinflation72 means the rate of inflation is decreasing. When disinflation occurs, inflation is still occurring—it is positive—but the rate of inflation in one year is lower than in the previous year. If inflation in 2011 is four percent and in 2012 it is three percent, then disinflation has occurred. Constant inflation means the rate of inflation is not changing. Prices are increasing, so there is inflation, but the inflation rate is not increasing. It stays 3% for several years at a time. Constant inflation is not too problematic, as people can adjust their behavior around predictable changes. Accelerating inflation means the rate of inflation is increasing. If the inflation rate is 5% one year and then 7% the following year, accelerating inflation is occurring. This is more harmful, as no one knows how much the rate will increase. Hyperinflation Disinflation a high rate of inflation - a decreasing rate of inflation “18%” “5%, 4%, 3%…” Accelerating Inflation Constant Inflation an increasing rate of inflation a stable rate of inflation over time “3%, 4%, 5%...” “3%, 3%, 3%” Another price index, the Producer Price Index (PPI) measures the prices of raw materials, and helps us to determine when the prices of the factors of production are rising. In the United States, the GDP Deflator is a more comprehensive price index meant to determine the “real” value of GDP over time. It measures a broader array of prices than the CPI or the PPI. The GDP deflator is determined by adding up a market basket of goods for each of two years. The baskets are priced according to what each would have cost in the base year. The total price of each basket differs, even though each is in base year dollars, because some of the goods in the current year either did not exist or were less common consumer items in the base year. With the GDP deflator, we measure inflation with a changing basket and fixed prices. We can calculate the GDP deflator as follows: GDP Deflator = price of current basket base year prices - price of base year basket base year prices price of base year basket base year prices We use the GDP deflator to factor inflation out of nominal GDP: 72 Don’t mix disinflation with deflation. They are two different things. x 100% ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 86 Real GDP = Nominal GDP GDP Deflator Suppose GDP is $100 billion in 2084, and the deflator is 220. Real GDP is found as follows: Real GDP2084 Real GDP2084 = Nominal GDP2084 GDP deflator = $100 billion 220% = $100 billion 2.2 = $45.5 billion Interest Rates One way banks earn profit is by charging interest on loans. The original loan amount is called the principal balance. Interest is added to the balance of the loan at given intervals. Interest is calculated on the entire balance: the original principal combined with any accumulated interest. Islam, Interest Rates, and a Different Way of Banking The topic is far too large to explore here, but it is worth noting that not all banks follow the ‘‘charging interest’’ model. Islamic banks, due to religious restrictions on interest, have had to find other ways to remain profitable. It is hard to find unbiased articles on the subject, but, if interested (no pun intended) in learning more, you might want to start here: http://www.american.com/archive/2007/march-april-magazinecontents/islamic-banking-is-it-really-kosher/ For instance, say you originally borrowed $10,000. Since then, you have incurred $2,000 of interest. Your next interest charge will be based on the entire balance of $12,000. The more frequent the interval at which interest compounds, the faster the balance will grow. If you borrow at an interest rate of 5% compounded yearly, then after a year you need to pay back the principal plus 5% interest. But if the rate is 5% compounded daily, you will owe much more. Financial institutions compound interest using different intervals. To make it easy to compare, most state the total interest rate per year. This measure is called the annual percentage yield, or APY. The nominal interest rate on a loan is the stated percentage rate of interest. If there were no inflation, then banks would actually earn nominal interest. However, for the past century, the U.S. has experienced varying degrees of inflation. The real interest rate is the value of the interest that banks actually earn—and debtors actually pay—when there is inflation. It is the difference between the nominal interest rate and the inflation rate. Real Interest Rate = Nominal Interest Rate --- Inflation Rate Many loans have flexible interest rates, which are determined by adding some arbitrary rate to the prime interest rate. The prime interest rate is the rate that banks charge on short-term loans to their most creditworthy corporate customers. The prime interest rate is published quarterly in the Wall Street Journal. The documents for loans that have flexible interest rates will indicate that the rate is determined ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 87 by adding some percentage to “the prime interest rate, as published in the Wall Street Journal.” When banks change the prime rate, they are adjusting for inflation. Roles of the Government in a Market Economy Even most free market economists agree there should be limits on what people should be able to do to make money—for example, the enslavement of children. There is no such thing as a “pure” market economy, or one that functions with zero government regulations and interventions. In most modern countries, the government steps in when the market cannot fulfill important social goals. (These goals vary by country; for example, some see health care as a right of all citizens, while others do not.) In the United States, most of us value breathing clean air. We value knowing we would continue to have some food and shelter, even in a severe depression. We value knowing we have some recourse if something happens to our property— or if we become disabled. Government intervention protects these values. Taxation is a second vital government function. To provide public goods and services, the government needs funding—so it collects taxes. Taxes affect the economy: they alter the prices of goods and services, they reduce how much people have to spend, and they result in incentives that can change behavior—for example, a tax deduction on mortgage interest encourages people to take loans to buy homes, and tax penalties on second children (best exemplified by China) can increase the number of single-child families. Promoting competition among buyers and sellers is a third government function. Laws protect buyers and sellers against anticompetitive practices. Most governments investigate and prosecute companies that commit anti-competitive behavior. Even when a company, such as Microsoft, escapes scrutiny in the United States, it may still be penalized for anti-competitive behavior elsewhere—for example, by the more socially progressive European Union. 73 Defense Against Aliens, and Other Public Goods One of the most critical government functions in a market economy is to provide and protect public goods. A public good (or service) is one for which it is impossible to distinguish private property rights. In other words, no one owns it-----and no one can own it. A pure public good is non-rivalrous and non-excludable. Non-rivalrous means that if one person takes some of a good, everyone else still has access to just as much of it. For example, if I breathe air, there is still plenty of air left for other people to breathe. (Unless we are stuck on a spacecraft.) If I download an episode of Dexter from iTunes, that doesn’t decrease the number of episodes you can download. Non-excludable means there is no way to stop people from taking or using a good or service. No one can be excluded from it. Air is both non-rivalrous and non-excludable. You can’t stop people from breathing it. But episodes of Dexter on iTunes are excludable: Apple can charge for downloads, and exclude people unwilling to pay.73 In fact, sometimes you can’t even exclude yourself from a public good-----such as national defense. If hostile aliens were to land in your town, the government would try to protect you-----even if you insisted you hadn’t paid taxes and didn’t deserve protection. The government may not provide us the air we breathe, but it regulates air quality-----ensuring the air is clean. Even goods that are not ‘‘pure’’ public goods-----such as national parks, which exclude some visitors with small entrance fees and are not completely non-rivalrous, since too many visitors at a time will damage them-----may still require government protection. Debate it! Resolved: That private firms should be allowed to compete without government regulation. Of course, people can work around such constraints—using services such as BitTorrent. But, technically, they could steal eggs from the market too; the eggs are still technically excludable. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 88 Private property rights are another important government responsibility. As you have learned, individuals must believe their rights to private property are being protected, or they will have no incentive to invent, to invest, to innovate, or to take entrepreneurial risks. The government is responsible for establishing and enforcing laws that protect private property. Providing income security and redistribution is another role of the government in a market economy. People cannot work forever or always; they grow old or they may lose their jobs. And some people can never work enough to support themselves or their families. In the United States, the government provides a modest Social Security income to the retired and the disabled by taxing those who work. It also assists the temporarily unemployed. Without the government as an intermediary, many selfinterested, rational people would not freely pool a portion of their income to support complete strangers. The government also provides aid to impoverished families with children (nicknamed “welfare”) as a social service that softens the harshness of the market system. To make all this possible, governments collect taxes from consumers and producers. Sales, Value Added, and Excise Taxes Some taxes are on the money people earn, others on the money that they spend. Sales, value added, and excise taxes fall on the spending side, and are therefore known as consumption taxes. Traditional sales taxes (still common in the United States) are levied on the final sale of most goods and services. If there is a 10% sales tax in a city, people will pay $1 of tax on a $10 good—driving the total price up to $11.74 Purchases for the purpose of resale—such as buying 100 DemiDec Cram Kits at Barnes and Noble in order to resell them to 100 other students—are exempt from sales taxes. A value added tax (VAT) is a nationwide sales tax (first introduced by the French in the 1950s) levied at each step in the production process. DemiDec would pay a certain amount of tax on the paper used to print the Cram Kits, Barnes and Noble would pay tax on the printed Cram Kits it bought from DemiDec to stock at the bookstore, you would pay tax on the Cram Kits you bought from Barnes and Noble to resell to your friends, and your friends would pay tax on the Cram Kits they bought from you. Supporters of the value added tax believe it limits fraud; with a sales tax, companies and consumers might try to pretend they plan to resell a product in order to avoid paying it, but with a value added tax there is no incentive to lie. It also generates revenue for the government even in countries where many people are unemployed or have low incomes, as long as they are consuming something. An excise tax is a special tax applied to each unit sold of a specific good or service. A government usually imposes excise taxes for one of two reasons. First, it might want to discourage consumption of a good by making it more expensive. Such “sin taxes” can apply to items such as alcohol and cigarettes that have negative externalities for consumer health— or for society. We’ll come back to this topic later when we discuss Pigovian taxes. Second, the government might be looking to generate revenue on items for which demand is priceinelastic. For example, travelers almost always need someplace to stay the night—so demand for hotels is relatively inelastic. Local governments therefore impose steep taxes on hotels, rental cars, and airplane 74 Some goods—often including raw fruits and vegetables, but not processed snacks such as Doritos—can be excluded from sales taxes if the government is trying to encourage people to buy them. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 89 tickets, because their impact on the number of units sold is minimal—and because most of the burden is felt by taxpayers from someplace else! Sales Taxes and Deadweight Loss The graph demonstrates the effect of a sales or excise tax on the market for a good—say, DECABARS. When the government enacts an excise tax of 20 cents, the cost of DECABARS rises by that amount for every bar sold. Essentially, the supply curve shifts to the left, from S1 to S2, 20 cents higher. The new equilibrium price is higher than the original price—in this example, it rises from $1.00 to $1.10. But wait: the tax was 20 cents, and price only rose 10 cents. That means producers are also absorbing some of the cost of the tax. Since consumers are paying more than they would be without the tax, and benefitting from a smaller number of goods, they sustain a loss of welfare, represented by the region B and C. Watch it on YouTube Deadweight loss is easiest to learn when you see it animated on screen. Check out this video lecture on YouTube: http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=9F6PSIOJQuU Since producers are earning less than they would be without the tax, they also sustain a loss of welfare, represented by the region D and E. The government collects revenue—in this case, 20 cents per each of the 40 units sold. The government’s revenue amounts to regions B and D. What happens to regions C and E? They are simply lost: consumers and producers no longer benefit from them, and the government doesn’t collect them. They are referred to as deadweight loss. All taxes have a fundamentally similar effect on buyers and sellers. Taxes raise the amount consumers pay and decrease the amount producers receive. They decrease the quantity exchanged, they generate revenue for the government, and they create a deadweight loss for society.75 “Tax incidence” and “tax burden” refer to who bears the welfare loss that results from a sales or excise tax. Tax incidence is usually shared between consumers and producers, but the degree to which it is shared varies by how price-elastic demand is. If demand is perfectly elastic, producers bear the tax burden—since any price increase will cause all consumers to leave the market. If demand is perfectly inelastic, consumers bear the whole tax burden, since producers can raise prices without affecting how much consumers choose to buy. 75 The government can try to compensate for this deadweight loss by using tax revenue effectively. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 90 Most goods lie between these extremes. The more price-elastic the demand, the more of a burden producers will bear. Consider charts A and B. Demand in A is very price-elastic, so a 20 cent tax is borne mostly by the producers—equilibrium price only rises 5 cents. Demand in B is relatively inelastic, so more of the burden falls on consumers: price rises 15 cents. Lump Sum and Property Taxes A lump sum tax requires everyone to pay the same amount. For example, all businesses in a certain region may be required to pay $150 in order to stay in operation—a so-called business license or registration fee. It may not be called a tax, but it effectively is one. In the United States, owners of land and buildings pay property tax, which is usually a fixed tax per some amount (usually $100) of assessed property value. A property tax is a tax on wealth, not income or spending. If you invest a million dollars in an apartment building, you will pay an annual property tax plus income tax on any income from renting out the apartments. If you invest a million dollars in a work of art, you will be charged a sales tax, but you won’t have to pay an art owner’s tax every year. Property taxes can influence the real estate market. If a city significantly raises its property taxes, fewer people will want to move there, and real estate prices will fall. Income Taxes The personal income tax is a tax on the money people earn as income each year. In the United States, it is a progressive tax made legal by the 16th amendment in 1913. It is progressive because, as a person’s income increases, he must pay a progressively larger percentage of his income in tax. To determine tax liability, the United States government divides people into income brackets. The more income you make, the higher your bracket, and the higher your marginal tax rate. Suppose we had 4 hypothetical income tax brackets: INCOME $0-10,000 $10,001-$20,000 $20,001-$50,000 $50,001 and up MARGINAL TAX RATE 0% 10% 20% 30% Someone who made $10,000 would pay zero tax76. Someone who made $15,000 would pay zero tax on the first $10,000 and 10 percent marginal tax on the remaining $5,000, for a total tax of $500. He would keep $14,500. Someone who made $25,000 would pay zero tax on the first $10,000, 10 percent on the next $10,000, and 20 percent on the last $5,000—or $2,000 in all. He would keep $23,000. Someone who made $100,000 would pay zero tax on the first $10,000, 10 percent on the next $10,000, 20 percent on the next $30,000, and 30 percent on the last $50,000—or $22,000 in all. He would keep $78,000. The actual tax brackets in the United States, as of 2010, were as follows: 76 This might upset certain presidential candidates. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 91 Marginal Tax Rate Single 10% $0-$8,375 15% $8,375-34,000 25% $34,000-82,400 28% $82,400-171,850 33% $171,850-373,650 35% $373,650+ Married Filing Jointly Married Filing Separately $0-$16,750 $0-$8,375 $16,750 -68,000 $8,375-34,000 $68,000-137,300 $34,000-68,650 $137,300-209,250 $68,650-104,625 $209,250-336,550 $104,625-186,825 $373,650+ $186,825+ Technically, married couples combining incomes confront higher tax rates than if filing separately. This is sometimes criticized as a marriage tax. Some critics of progressive tax systems argue all people should be the taxed at the same proportional or flat rate—say, 20%. The drawback to this approach is that taking away 20% of a struggling person’s limited salary would probably have a much greater impact on him or her than taking away 20% of a wealthy person’s enormous investment income. In this way, a flat tax is actually regressive. A regressive tax is one that costs those with fewer resources a greater proportion of their income. For example, if all people must pay $100 each to vote for president, it costs poor citizens a relatively greater portion of their resources to vote. Your average Bill might only have a thousand dollars in savings, while Bill Gates might have five hundred million. Promoting Competition In the United States, the Constitution grants Congress the power to regulate interstate and international commerce: “to regulate commerce with foreign nations, and among the several states, and with the Indian tribes.” This portion of the Constitution is referred to as the “Commerce Clause.” Traditionally, Congress and the Supreme Court have interpreted the interstate commerce clause to allow wide-ranging federal jurisdiction; after all, most large transactions do involve more than one state. Debate it! Resolved: That all people should be taxed at the same rate. Coase Theorem Suppose you use high speed Internet to run an online poker business in your bedroom-----and you use so much bandwidth that you’re slowing down the Internet for your neighbor, Susan. Susan wants to receive photos of her new grandson, but they come in so slowly that she is more and more frustrated. Worse, the slow Internet is making it hard for her to research, write, and get paid for freelance magazine articles. The traditional solution to a problem like this one-----a negative externality-----would be for the government (or some other party) to regulate Internet usage. You might be forbidden from using more than 500 gigabytes of bandwidth per day, or taxed $10 for every gigabyte you go beyond that. The solution works-----but the economist Ronald Coase realized there might be another way. What if your neighbor paid you enough to make it worth your while to rent a server somewhere else? For Susan, the loss of utility from receiving photos of her grandson-----and the lost revenue from writing magazine articles-----makes it totally worthwhile to hand you, say, $100 per month to rent a remote server. And, for you, the remote server would have no impact on revenue, so why not accept the $100? Coase’s remarkable insight-----now known as the Coase Theorem-----was that it didn’t matter who owned what in the initial state-----as long as the parties involved in a situation have clear property rights and can negotiate easily and freely, with zero transaction costs, they will reach an efficient solution. Read more about the Coase theorem-----including its implications for divorce law-----here: http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Coase.html Unfortunately, most externalities are not so easily resolved. Property rights are not always so explicit (who owns the air, or the right to a climate-change-free world?), and transactions and negotiations can be costly and complicated, especially when many parties are involved. Congressional power is necessary to curb the power of monopolies because the government would be unable to enforce antitrust law if it did not have ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 92 jurisdiction. United States antitrust law was codified in the 1890 Sherman Antitrust Act and the 1914 Clayton Antitrust Act. At first the Sherman Antitrust Act was used to restrain labor unions while monopolies ran free. More recently, it has been used more effectively to restrict monopolies. Section 1 restricts collusive agreements such as backroom deals to fix prices. Section 2 makes it illegal to monopolize a market. The Clayton Antitrust Act was passed to protect labor unions while more directly targeting real anticompetitive business behavior. The Clayton Act prohibits mergers that would substantially lessen competition or create a monopoly. When two airlines try to merge, the government studies the market very carefully to en sure the merger will not lessen competition and hurt consumers. Similar laws exist in most economies. However, most constitutions grant their governments the power to regulate all commerce, regardless of whether it is “interstate.” The United States is not the only government with an emphasis on state’s rights (neighboring Mexico has a similar structure) but it is one of the most extreme. Positive and Negative Externalities of Public Policy An externality occurs whenever an economic transaction has a side effect on someone other than the buyer or seller—a side effect that neither party pays for. That side effect can be positive or negative. The most common example of a negative externality is pollution. A power plant might expel poisonous waste into a river, killing its fish and hurting the economy of a village downstream. When the plant decides how much energy to produce, it only considers its own costs and revenues and does not consider the cost of pollution to the village. The power plant staff underestimates the real cost of producing power—and produces more than the socially ideal amount. If you buy a hybrid Toyota Prius to save on fuel costs, it improves the quality of life for everyone else in the form of cleaner air.77 If enough people in a community pay to be vaccinated for the flu, those who didn’t pay for the vaccination also become less likely to catch it—because there are fewer people left through whom the flu can spread. Or, consider my friend Craig’s purchase of a home in Boston. It was in a less than prosperous neighborhood. A few years after he bought it, the Massachusetts Bay Transportation Authority opened a new subway station nearby, making it possible to commute easily into Central Boston. Home prices shot up and businesses saw a surge in customers. The opening of a subway station had positive externalities for everyone already in the neighborhood—but they paid nothing more for it than any other taxpayer in the state. To combat negative externalities, or to encourage positive externalities, economists and policy-makers devise market incentive programs. All power plants might be given a limited number of pollution credits, with the ability to trade credits with other power plants. Cleaner power plants could make a profit by selling their right to pollute to dirtier power plants. Such policies give producers an economic incentive to pollute less. The government may try to make decision-makers incorporate social costs into actual accounting costs, “internalizing” them. Carbon dioxide contributes to global warming and is produced in many different ways; some goods are associated with more carbon dioxide production, some with less. This is a cost 77 It would also lower gas prices for everyone (through decreased demand). ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 93 that most people do not consider when choosing what to buy. The government could implement a carbon tax that would increase the cost of all products made in ways that contribute carbon dioxide to the atmosphere. Non-polluting products which would ordinarily cost more than their polluting counterparts would become a better value. Such behavior-modifying excise taxes are sometimes referred to as Pigovian taxes. When something has a positive externality, its benefits are undervalued, so the market produces less than the socially optimal quantity. The government may choose to give subsidies or tax breaks to encourage the production and consumption of such goods and services. Social Security The Social Security system began in the United States with the passage of the 1935 Social Security Act as part of Franklin D. Roosevelt’s New Deal. The Social Security tax is a payroll tax; employers and the employees both pay a percentage of the employee’s income into the Social Security program. The system has worked relatively well, but now economists are predicting a problem. When the program began, Americans did not live as long, and they had more babies—so the average length of retirement was shorter, and there were more young people around working. The ratio of workers to older beneficiaries was over 30 to 1. Right now, there are about 3.5 workers to every beneficiary; in 2020 there will be about 2.5. Since the payments of current workers are transferred immediately to current beneficiaries, it will be difficult for the proportionally shrinking pool of workers 15 years from now to keep financing all of Social Security. Let’s go over one more time: current workers are transferring funds to the currently retired with their current tax dollars. When a person pays taxes into Social Security, those taxes are used immediately. The funds a person pays are not saved for his or her own retirement. In some systems, such as in Chile, people have own government-allocated retirement accounts that pay their own funds back to them when they retire—amounting to government-run investment accounts. Critics note that, while this plan sounds good during boom times when the stock market is rising, at other times it could lead to people losing their retirement savings to stock market declines. In the United States, as the large baby-boomer generation continues to retire, there will most likely need to be less paid out by Social Security (reduced benefits or increased age requirement) or more taken in (higher taxes). Neither option has many champions; solutions remain elusive78. The American Welfare System The modern welfare system first took shape in the United States following the Great Depression. It was intended to provide workers with money if they became unemployed. It was also designed, through public works projects, to provide jobs in a faltering economy. By putting money into the hands of cashstrapped consumers, the government hoped to stimulate aggregate demand and boost production levels for the economy. The theory was that the artificial stimulus would provide a needed jumpstart to the economy, as if it were a car with a dead battery. Once revived, the economy—like the car—would propel itself forward from there. 78 Former President Clinton recently noted on The Daily Show that this problem should ease as soon as people his age die out, since Americans, especially recent immigrants, are actually having a fair number of babies again. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 94 From the 1930s through the mid-1990s, Debate it! a program called Aid to Families with Resolved: That the unemployed should not be permitted to have Dependent Children (AFDC) assisted additional children until they find jobs and can support them. poor families in the United States. It had few work requirements of those who received benefits, gave more money to families with more children, and placed no time limits on benefits. This often meant benefits were collected indefinitely, since, as critics observed, there was little incentive to start working for limited wages and thereby lose the benefits. If a rational person could do nothing for $150 per week or work hard to receive $200 per week while also paying for childcare, he or she would probably choose to do nothing. A rational person might also have more children to increase welfare payments. The 1996 Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act (PRWORA)—passed by President Clinton—aimed to repair these misplaced incentives. It replaced AFDC with Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF), which limits most welfare recipients to five years. TANF also has higher work requirements, and it gave states more flexibility in how to administer their welfare programs. President Obama recently increased this flexibility for states, provided they continue to show enough welfare recipients finding work. The number of American families on welfare fell significantly from the all-time-high of 5.1 million in 1994 to about 2 million in 2000. Some economists believe the decline was less the result of welfare reform than it was the happy byproduct of increased employment opportunities and higher minimum wages during the boom times of the 1990s. More recently, TANF has been criticized for providing benefits to only about 40% of eligible families, and during the recent global economic crisis it has come under increased pressure to service the growing numbers of American families in need. Unemployment Compensation Unemployment compensation (also Debate it! known as unemployment insurance) Resolved: That unemployment benefits should be limited to two years. provides payments for a brief period to workers who have been fired or laid off. Its purpose is to provide people with a financial base while they try to find a new job. The economic argument for unemployment insurance is that it keeps people from being desperate enough to apply for welfare or to take jobs that don’t suit them. Imagine an aerospace engineer being fired and then taking a job picking grapes because she has to support her family—and then being so busy picking grapes she can’t hunt for another engineering job. This poor allocation of labor resources would leave the economy producing below the production possibilities frontier. Unemployment compensation is intended to smooth the transition from job to job so that the economy can fully employ all its scarce resources. In the United States, unemployment compensation comes from a mix of federal and state programs. At the federal level, it was first part of the Social Security Act of 1935. States also manage their own unemployment programs. The specifics, such as who is eligible, how much recipients receive, and how long they can qualify, are determined by both state and federal law. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 95 Fiscal Policy In a mixed market system, the federal government uses fiscal policy to influence economic activity. Fiscal policy consists of government taxation and spending in order to influence aspects of the larger economy, like productivity, inflation and unemployment. Income taxes, government expenditures, transfer payments, and the size of the deficit are all part of fiscal policy. In general, the goal of fiscal policy is economic stability. The government hopes to use its powers of borrowing, spending, and collecting to soften the impact of the business cycle. The government has two categories of fiscal policy tools. Automatic stabilizers adjust on their own in response to changes in the business cycle. For example, the personal income tax is an automatic stabilizer. In a recession, people earn less income—so pay less in tax. A person whose annual income falls $10,000 will really only lose $7,000 if that lost income would have been taxed at 30%. As we saw above, welfare systems that deliver money to the unemployed also help keep people adding to economic activity. Discretionary fiscal policy involves deliberate government efforts to influence economic activity in a specific way—such as with a stimulus package to cut taxes and create more jobs. The first major fiscal policy advocate was the economist John Maynard Keynes. In fact, many people use the terms “fiscal policy” and “Keynesian policy” interchangeably. Keynes noted that, as part of the natural business cycle, the economy does not always reach full employment. If a recession worsens enough, there will be many people who want jobs but cannot find them. GDP will decrease, and, because overall income will decline, consumers won’t have enough money to start the cycle of increased spending that could spiral the economy upward again. Recovery might take a long time. Classical economists believed the government should try as much as possible to balance its own budget during a recession, so as not to interfere with the “invisible hand” working everything out. Keynes disagreed. He believed there was an economic reason for intervening. A recession, he said, was caused by poor coordination leading to non-optimal choices. How could it make sense to have so many factories and laborers idle? Even if the invisible hand could work things out in the long run, Keynes famously pointed that “in the long run, we’re all dead.” Why not act sooner? Keynes theorized that if the government stepped in and injected extra spending into the circular flow, this spending could jumpstart an upward spiral. As an economy recovered, the government could gradually lower its spending and let private consumption lead the way. He argued that if the government were well-informed it could even increase spending before a recession or depression ever took hold—the fiscal equivalent of preventive medicine. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 96 Expansionary fiscal policy is the use of government spending to stimulate aggregate demand and spark an economic upturn. To expand economic activity, it can: Increase Government Spending (G). This injects more money into the spending cycle, increasing aggregate demand. As more goods and services are needed, more people are hired to produce them. Unemployment falls, GDP rises, and the price level rises, too. Lower Taxes. Lower taxes leave consumers with more disposable income. They spend more, so aggregate demand shifts to the right. Unemployment falls; GDP rises. Remember the multiplier effect. If the government injects money into the system, be it by buying airplanes or by hiring people to fix bridges and schools, the increase in economic activity includes not just the injection itself, but all the exchanges based on the money it adds to the economy. Contractionary fiscal policy refers to government efforts to slow an economy, usually to fight inflation, by cutting back aggregate demand. It can: Decrease Government Spending. Lowering G removes money from the spending cycle, thereby reducing aggregate demand. Unemployment rises; GDP falls. Raise Taxes. Higher taxes mean consumers have less disposable income—so they spend less. The aggregate demand curve shifts to the left. Unemployment rises; GDP falls. Federal Taxes in the United States This is a good time to step aside and consider government taxes and spending more carefully. Like many policy choices, they vary among countries. Here, we consider the United States. Tax revenues come from a variety of sources. Some revenues are pooled into a general fund, from which the government spends money however it sees fit. Other collections are earmarked for certain uses; the government cannot use earmarked funds for anything other than their intended purpose. Sources of U.S. government revenue include: Personal income taxes. As described earlier, the United States has a progressive income tax, with higher income brackets charged higher rates. The chart shows the tax brackets for 2010; brackets change regularly to account for inflation. Personal income taxes account for about half of federal tax revenues. Corporate income taxes. Just as individuals are obligated to pay taxes on personal income, most corporations must pay taxes on profits. Consumption taxes. As discussed earlier, consumption taxes—including sales taxes, value added taxes, and excise taxes—are taxes on the purchase of goods. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 97 Import taxes or “duties.” Duties are collected on the sale of certain imported goods. Estate and gift taxes. These tax wealth that is inherited or given to another person. Capital gains taxes. These tax the profits from the sale of investments such as stocks and property. Some countries charge higher taxes on short-term capital gains—usually defined as investments held for less than year—to help promote a stable investment environment. Some examples of earmarked taxes include: Payroll taxes. Payroll taxes include Social Security and Medicare taxes. Both are deducted from employee paychecks. All payroll tax collections are employer-matched; that is, half of what is collected is deducted from employee pay and the other half is paid by employers. Critics complain that this hurts the self-employed, who must pay it all themselves. Payroll taxes do not enter the General Revenue Fund. User fees. We pay fees for the use of airports, highways, national parks, etc. The fees we pay are earmarked to be re-invested in those locations. The funds collected from user fees do not enter the General Revenue Fund. Shortcomings of Fiscal Policy Some critics believe government spending “crowds out” private investment, limiting its effectiveness. Others note that it takes a long time for fiscal policy to pass through the legislature and the bureaucracy. By the time a measure is enacted, a crisis may already be over. Also, because fiscal policy is the domain of elected politicians, it may suffer from or be accused of political bias. For instance, in 2011, President Obama proposed the American Jobs Act, a fiscal policy package— combining spending increases and tax cuts—meant to generate jobs in an economy on the precipice of a second recession in as many years. “Pass this bill,” he declared over and over again in the weeks that followed, but he probably knew it stood almost no chance of passing in a Republican-controlled House of Representatives. Fiscal policy, whether good or bad, is easily politicized—and stalled. Budget Deficit and National Debt When expenditures exceed revenues—that is, when outlays exceed receipts—there is a budget deficit. If To finance a budget deficit, the federal government must issue and sell debt securities. National debt is receipts exceed outlays, there is a budget surplus. the accumulation of outstanding debt securities. Generally, deficits and surpluses refer to a single year’s finances. The United States federal government has run a deficit over most of the past fifty years. The recent exception was the period from 1998 to 2001, when the government ran a surplus under President Clinton. At its peak, the surplus was $236 billion in 2000. Afterward, the federal government relapsed into deficits—spurred largely by significant tax cuts and increased military spending under President Bush. The deficit was $412 billion in 2004 and a record $482 billion by the time President Obama took office in 2008; it has continued to grow since. Congress cannot pull money out of thin air. To run a deficit, the Treasury must take a loan: it issues and sells bills, bonds, notes, and other securities. Some of the debt is sold to other government agencies that are running surpluses. Some is bought by the Federal Reserve. Much is held by foreign nations. The rest is bought and held by the American public. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 98 Each time the United States federal government runs a budget deficit, the government issues and sells long-term debt securities. When there is a surplus, it can be used to repay outstanding debt. But when there is a deficit, it accumulates into the outstanding debt. The accumulation of all outstanding debt securities is the national debt. By the end of fiscal year 2003, the national debt was around $6.78 trillion. On Thanksgiving Day 2010, it was $13.8 trillion. In 2011, Congress hesitated before passing its usual law to raise the debt ceiling—the maximum amount the United States government can borrow at any one time. The result was great political and economic uncertainty, and a downgrading of United States credit. The Federal Reserve System The Money Panic of 1907 prompted Congress to consider creating a national banking system, which the United States had lacked for seventy years. In response to the prodding of President Woodrow Wilson, Congress finally passed the Federal Reserve Act of 1913. It was a compromise between those who wanted centralized control of money and those who did not. The resulting Federal Reserve System is not one bank, but is divided into twelve districts, each with its own bank. There are also 25 smaller branch banks. For the most part, “the Fed” operates independently of other parts of government. By law, all national banks—banks operating in more than one state—must belong to the Federal Reserve System. State banks may elect to do so. Only about a third of American banks belong to the Federal Reserve, though this number is rising as more banks merge across state lines. The Federal Reserve has six main functions: Determine and conduct monetary policy Supervise and regulate financial institutions Lend to banks and other financial institutions Serve as a bank for the U.S. Government Issue cash (currency and coins) Offer services, such as clearing checks, to financial institutions The Federal Reserve System Board of Governors Federal Open Market Committee Federal Advisory Council 12 Federal Reserve District Banks 25 Federal Reserve Branch Banks Member Banks At the head of the Federal Reserve is seven-member group called the Board of Governors. Each member is appointed to a 14-year term by the President, with one term ending every two years. To ensure geographical representation, no two members can be from the same Federal Reserve District. The Board of Governors supervises the banking system and money supply. It also rules on proposed bank mergers. The President appoints the Chairman of the Federal Reserve. Bush appointee Ben Bernanke replaced long-time chairman Alan Greenspan in 2006 and was confirmed to a second four-year term by President Obama. Bernanke has had the hefty responsibility of steering the nation’s monetary policy through the economic crisis that began in 2008. The twelve district banks are a holdover from the fear of centralized banking power; today, instant communication makes the existence of twelve separate banks less meaningful. They effectively act as a single entity. The district banks are technically owned by their member banks; every commercial bank in the Federal Reserve System must purchase shares of stock in its local Federal Reserve Bank. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 99 The twelve-member Federal Open Market Committee meets monthly in Washington and manages the purchase and sale of government bonds and securities on the open market. Seven of its members are drawn from the Board of Governors for the entire Federal Reserve. The other five are presidents of regional Federal Reserve Banks. The New York District Bank president is a permanent member. The Federal Advisory Council is another committee of twelve, all prominent commercial bankers. Each district chooses one person to represent it each year; representatives ordinarily serve three one-year terms before stepping down. The Federal Advisory Council meets four times annually. Although the council cannot set policy, it helps maintain communication between leaders charged with maintaining the national money supply and profit-seeking bankers who operate under their policies. Monetary Policy Goals and the Employment Act of 1946 The broad mission of the Federal Reserve is to pursue (through monetary policy) the economic goals of the United States. These goals include price stability, full employment, and economic growth. The Employment Act of 1946 and the Humphrey-Hawkins Act of 1978 helped define these goals. The Employment Act of 1946 charged the government with the responsibility of creating and maintaining full employment, a situation in which just about everyone who wants a job has one. The act did not define a specific target employment rate, however. The 1978 Humphrey-Hawkins Act (also known as the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act) presented more concrete goals: It defines four percent unemployment as the highest acceptable unemployment level. If at all possible, the government should balance the federal budget. The government should try to improve the balance of trade. The Federal Reserve Board and Federal Open Market Committee are responsible for maintaining economic growth. At least once each year, the President is required to inform Congress of his economic targets and his plans to implement them. At least twice each year, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board must inform Congress of his money supply targets and his plans to implement them. The Humphrey-Hawkins Act expired in 2000, but many of its provisions have continued informally. One that has not is the requirement that the Federal Reserve set targets for money supply growth. In 2000, the Federal Reserve announced that the money supply is no longer an accurate measure of economic prosperity or, on its own, an effective guide for monetary policy. Monetary Policy ----- History and Methods Where the rest of the government uses fiscal policy to pursue economic goals, the Federal Reserve and other central banks use monetary policy. Monetary policy describes any effort to increase or decrease the money supply; by contrast, fiscal policy focuses on changing aggregate demand.) To understand its place in the scheme of things, we need to consider the history of economic policy. In the beginning, there was classical economics, sparked by Adam Smith and his “invisible hand”. Classical economists urged governments to ignore the temptation to tamper with their economies; ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 100 laissez faire was the way to go. During a recession, classical economists argued, wages would fall, and eventually businesses would hire workers again from the newly cheap labor pool, bringing down unemployment and restarting the cycle of rising economic activity. Helpful business investments would also tend to increase with falling interest rates. That status quo mostly endured until the Great Depression. Then economies tumbled as governments stood by with their invisible hands tied behind their backs—until John Keynes unshackled them with proposals for active fiscal intervention. Governments upped their spending, hoping to restore aggregate demand. Keynesian economics dominated the world for decades. Then, in the 1960s, a new theory, monetarism, challenged Keynesian wisdom. Milton Friedman, an economist at the University of Chicago, had conducted research connecting the money supply to the health of the economy over a span of many years. He found that periods of too little money in the economy correlated with recessions or depressions. Periods of too much money correlated with inflation. Friedman contended the ultimate cause of the Great Depression was the destruction of the money supply. The combined effect of the stock market crash, panicked bank runs, and the closure of banks was a drastic decrease in the nation’s money supply.79 Earlier, we showed how banks help to multiply money and direct idle savings towards investments. To understand Friedman’s theory, which became known as monetarism, imagine what would happen if many people suddenly withdrew their money from banks and stuffed it in their pillows. The multiplier would take a severe hit. Since monetarists believe a reduction in the money supply is the main cause of recession, they believe the best way to restore a down economy is to expand the money supply. The reason fiscal policy seems to work, they argue, is that it does expand the money supply. But it is inefficient because it relies on the government to decide what to spend on and whom to reward with tax cuts. The infusion of money into the economy may focus on government priorities instead of on what consumers and suppliers want— and may overshoot its goal, leading to inflation. According to Friedman, the best way to help the economy grow in a stable way is to maintain a slow, steady increase in the money supply. Friedman suggested a two or three percent annual increase to allow gradual economic growth while discouraging inflation. By the early 1970s, many economists had accepted this theory and governments began to give more power to their central banks.80 Friedman’s most important contribution to economic policy was a simple equation of exchange that relates the money supply, the velocity of money, GDP, and the overall level of prices in an economy: (M)(V) = (P)(Q) 79 This was in the era before the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) guaranteed a certain amount of every bank account (currently $250,000). Similar organizations and guarantees now exist around the world. 80 This does not mean Keynesian theory has been forgotten, as recent stimulus packages in the United States have shown. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 101 The velocity of money is how quickly it is spent. How many times in the course of a year does the average dollar (or peso, or pound) change hands? People and firms do not always spend their money immediately. Suppose the average household or business holds a dollar for two months. It would take about four months for each dollar to circulate through the economy: two months held by consumers, two months held by businesses. The result: a velocity of 3, since each dollar circulates through the economy three times per year. What if habits changed, and businesses and households held onto a dollar for an average of three months every time it was spent or earned? Each dollar would complete a circular flow every six months. The velocity of money would be 2. (M)(V) = (P)(Q) M = Money Supply V = Velocity of Money P = general Price Level Q = quantity of goods (GDP) Velocity of Money (M2) in the United States It is straightforward to calculate GDP once you know the amount of money in an economy and its velocity. Consider the imaginary country of Bieber. There is only $1000 in circulation in Bieber. If the velocity of money in Bieber is 5, each of those dollars will be spent on goods and services and reearned by workers five times each year. $1,000 times 5 equals $5,000 of goods and services bought in a year. GDP would be $5,000. However, there is a third factor: the price level. If the money supply suddenly doubled to $2,000, the velocity of 5 would then give us a GDP of $10,000, seemingly doubling the economic output of the nation. But what if it turned out prices in Bieber had doubled, too? An item that cost two dollars last year now costs four. Real GDP would have stayed the same even as GDP appeared to double. Thus, the dollar amount of GDP is misleading. In our equation of exchange, P can rise instead of or along with Q—producing some degree of inflation instead of just increased GDP. Friedman’s research indicated the velocity of money tends to remain fairly constant. If you examine the equation of exchange, you will see that if velocity doesn’t change, one needs only to change the money supply to affect the nation’s GDP (provided that inflation is under control). If both the price level and velocity are constant, increasing the money supply by five percent means GDP will rise by five percent, too. Decreasing the money supply 10 percent decreases GDP 10 percent. Nothing is that easy, however. History has shown us that velocity does change. Check out the chart. During the recent economic crisis velocity slowed down significantly, as people held onto their money in times of uncertainty—and it surged during the boom years of the Clinton presidency, when Americans were spending more often on more things (including dot-com stocks!) Also, inflation is almost always going to raise prices at least a bit each year, and increasing the money supply too quickly will tend to increase prices more than it does GDP. But, according to Friedman, if a ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 102 country adheres to a policy of slow, steady increases in the money supply, it will tend to see equally steady economic growth. Monetary Policy Tools Like its counterparts in other countries, the Federal Reserve has three main tools for implementing monetary policy changes. Open market operations refer to the buying and selling of government securities or bonds. They are so named because the Federal Reserve buys and sells them on the open market. If the Federal Reserve believes the money supply should be increased, it buys bonds, injecting money into the economy. If it believes there is too much money in the economy, it sells bonds, taking money out of circulation. Open market operations are the most commonly used monetary tool in the United States. Purchasing bonds and securities—Money supply increases. Selling bonds and securities—Money supply decreases. The discount rate is the interest rate the Federal Reserve charges when it lends money to banks. By lowering the discount rate, the Federal Reserve decreases banks’ costs of borrowing, thereby allowing banks to lower the rates for their own loans to consumers and firms. As per the law of demand, this causes a greater quantity of loans to be taken. If banks make more loans, then people have more money in their hands to spend. Lowering the discount rate therefore increases the money supply. The Federal Reserve also sets the Federal Funds Rate, which is the maximum rate of interest charged by one commercial bank when lending to another commercial bank; changes in the Federal Funds Rate tend to reflect those in the discount rate and have a similar effect. Lowering the Discount or Federal Funds Rate—Money supply increases Raising the Discount or Federal Funds Rate: Money supply decreases The reserve requirement is the percentage of deposits a bank must keep on reserve. If the Federal Reserve lowers this requirement, the money supply increases—since banks can loan out more funds. Increasing the Reserve Requirement—Money supply decreases. Decreasing the Reserve Requirement—Money supply increases. Suppose a bank has 5 clients each with $10,000 deposited in a checking account. It owes $10,000 to every depositor, so the bank has $50,000 in liabilities. Any depositor can demand back all of his money at any time. Of course, not everyone will (certainly not at the same time), so the bank does not have to keep all of it on hand, or in reserve. Money Multiplier Multiplier = 1/R Total Increase In Money Supply = A/R R = Reserve Requirement A = Initial Amount of Increase At a minimum, a bank must have in reserve the percentage specified by the reserve requirement. In our example, total deposits were $50,000. If the reserve requirement is 10%, the bank must keep $5,000 on hand. It can lend out the other $45,000. If the bank lends all $45,000, recipients of the loans now have an additional $45,000 in their hands to spend. Suppose the Federal Reserve lowers the reserve requirement to 2%. The bank is only required to keep $1,000 cash on hand. It can lend out another $4,000. This additional “new” money can be spent, too. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 103 Bank loans can have an even broader effect on the money supply. Assume a reserve requirement of 20%. A bank loans $100,000 of excess reserves to various people. These people probably took the loans in order to spend them. When they purchase items, the recipients of the money will deposit it in their own accounts. This means demand deposits at other banks increase by $100,000. These banks, in turn, can loan out $80,000. The cycle repeats: the money is re-loaned, re-spent, then re-deposited at banks that can loan out 80% of it. And so on. 81 We can develop a formula for this multiplier in the money supply: 1/r, where r is the required reserve ratio. For the above example, the money multiplier is 1 divided by 0.2, which yields 5. The initial loan of $100,000 will increase the volume of money in the economy by up to 5 times, or $500,000. As with the spending multiplier, the real money multiplier is not quite as high as the formula implies. Our calculation assumes all banks will loan out all the money they can. It also ignores taxes removing some of the money at each exchange, and the fact that people might not spend the entirety of their loans. But it gives us a sense of the impact a single change in the money supply can have. Money, Supply and Demand Just as with a product or service, the equilibrium price and quantity of money in the economy can be found by looking at supply and demand. To the right is a supply and demand diagram. This time, the “good” is money itself. The vertical axis, as usual, represents price. The price of money is the interest rate you must pay to borrow it. The horizontal axis represents the quantity of money in the economy. Assume the current equilibrium of supply and demand sets the money supply at M0. If the Federal Reserve pursues policies to tighten, or decrease, the money supply, the new supply curve will shift inward. In our example, it will move from S0 to S2. Interest rates rise (here, from 9% to 15%), and fewer people are willing to borrow. If fewer people borrow, less money is created, dropping the money supply from M0 to M2—and thereby limiting economic activity. If the Federal Reserve instead pursues a loose money policy, something designed to increase the money supply, the supply curve for money would shift outward, perhaps from M0 to M1. The new equilibrium would sport lower interest rates (here, 6%). If interest rates drop, more people will borrow money, increasing the amount of money in circulation, and augmenting economic activity. Less Direct Controls over the Money Supply in the United States The following Federal Reserve policies tend to have a less significant impact on money supply than the above more directly quantitative techniques. 81 This should remind you of the spending multiplier (related to the marginal propensity to consume). ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 104 Setting the Margin Requirement for Stocks. When a person buys a share of stock worth $100, he may not need to provide all the cash up front. He can also purchase the stock “on the margin”— paying, say, $10 of the $100, and letting the stockbroker loan him the difference. The Federal Reserve Board of Governors has the power to set the minimum percentage one must pay to purchase stocks. Raising this margin requirement would lessen speculation in stocks, stabilizing the money supply and the economy. A low margin requirement would encourage more speculation, since little money would be required up front when buying stocks. Setting Consumer and Real Estate Credit Standards. In rare times of emergency, Congress has given the Board of Governors the power to set restraints on consumer credit, such as minimum down payments on real estate loans and maximum length of repayment for loans. During World War II, overall spending soared, but the number of consumer goods available declined because the government channeled the majority of economic activity into weapons and war supplies. Civilian consumers were still earning wages, but the government did not want the economy to shift back to consumer goods. If the supply of consumer goods kept falling, the prices of everyday items would rise sharply. By setting a higher required down payment on mortgages and requiring loans to be paid off quickly, the Federal Reserve discouraged consumer borrowing. Interest rate ceilings. Under Regulation Q, the Board of Governors can establish a ceiling on interest rates commercial banks pay consumers on their time deposits. Usually, the ceiling is so high the market rate set by banks is far below it. In other words, the ceiling seldom has any effect. Moral suasion. Another unofficial method the Federal Reserve uses to implement its policies involves “friendly persuasion” or “arm twisting”. This moral suasion may take the form of public pronouncements, policy statements, and direct appeals. In the 1950s, for example, faced with the Korean War, the Federal Reserve asked banks to limit non-war-related lending to consumers in order to keep inflation down. Discussions between the Federal Reserve and specific banks may resemble threats if the situation is serious. If banks oblige, they may be rewarded in the future. Key Terms “Loose Money” “Easy Money” “Expansionary Money Policy” All of these refer to anything the Federal Reserve does to increase the money supply. The result will tend to be an increase in economic activity. This is often accompanied by lower unemployment, higher GDP, and higher inflation. “Tight Money” “Hard Money” “Contractionary Money Policy” All of these refer to anything the Federal Reserve does to decrease the money supply. The result will tend to be a decrease in economic activity. This is often accompanied by higher unemployment, lower GDP, and lower inflation. Advantages of Monetary Policy Swift enactment of policy. In the United States, changes in monetary policy can be implemented immediately via the sale or purchase of securities and bonds. The Federal Reserve’s other tools, such as changes in the discount rate, are also easy to implement during monthly meetings of the Board of Governors. No complicated politics: just quick action. When you compare this to the obstacles ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 105 fiscal policy faces in Congress, the Federal Reserve’s advantage becomes very clear. Even when fiscal policies have quick, dramatic effects, it can take a long time to legislate them. Politically acceptable tight policies. If the best policy is to slow the economy down, what elected politician will want to vote for a tax increase or a cut in spending? Politicians want to be reelected; even necessary tax hikes or spending cuts are exploited by their opponents to make them look bad. Monetary policy, set by the banking system, does not put a target on their backs. Economic experts make the decisions. The average politician probably understands less economics than someone who has read and understood this resource. Remember, the skills required to be elected are different than the skills required to manage a large economy. Easier to fine-tune policy. The Federal Reserve can change interest in rates in small increments, allowing it to guide the economy to a “soft landing” or to accelerate it gradually. Typical fiscal policy, such as tax cuts and spending increases, are more like hitting the problem with a hammer. Their exact impact is difficult to predict or control. Disadvantages of Monetary Policy You can’t push on a string. Tight money policy works well. If banks make less money available, fewer dollars exist, and economic activity slows down. Loose money policies are harder to execute. They make more money available in the form of cheaper loans, but if a depressed public does not want loans banks’ excess reserves just sit there. The money supply is unaffected. Fiscal policy, on the other hand, can put money directly into the hands of consumers (through tax cuts and transfer payments), and can directly add to consumption (through government purchases). Commercial banks and private companies can offset monetary policies. The ownership and purchasing of government bonds can lessen the effect of some monetary policies. For example, from 1955 to 1957, the Federal Reserve pursued a tight money policy. To maintain cash reserves, banks and corporations sold some of their bonds, allowing them more money, especially for business investment (I). When, in 1958, the Federal Reserve turned to a loose money policy, corporations bought back the government securities, decreasing available money supply. Changes in velocity. As discussed, consumer expectations can change velocity. If consumers expect prosperous times, they tend not to worry about keeping as much cash on hand. It is spent more quickly, raising V. If consumers expect a recession, they become more cautious, keeping more cash on hand, and lowering V. Consumer confidence levels are surveyed to gauge this. Non-bank financial institutions can lessen the effects of monetary policy. Savings and Loans, credit unions, personal finance companies, and financial institutions abroad are not controlled by the Federal Reserve. When the Federal Reserve pursues a tight money policy, these other institutions will loan out more money, since they can make more profits at higher interest rates. This works against the Federal Reserve’s policies to contract the money supply. Difficulty controlling cost-push inflation. If inflation results from higher prices of inputs (such as oil) controlling the money supply has little effect. Too much spending is not the problem. Impact on investment not always clear. Individual consumption (C) is not affected much by changes in the money supply. Investment (I) is, but there are also other factors that influence it. For example, during a boom, the Federal Reserve will raise interest rates to slow down growth. But, ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 106 during a boom, business optimism is high, so investors may decide to take out loans even at higher interest rates. Also, many corporations have enough market power (especially in monopolies and oligopolies) that they can pass the cost of higher interest to their consumers. Time for monetary policy to take effect. It takes time for changes in monetary policy to filter into the economy. For expansions or contractions of the money supply to be felt, several cycles of loanmaking or paying off loans must take place. Fiscal policy’s effects are more immediate. Other Notable Economists Phillips Curve In the 1950s, Kiwi82 economist William Phillips devoted himself to studying unemployment and wage changes over the last century of British history. He quickly noticed an inverse correlation: when wages were rising the most quickly, the rate of unemployment was lowest. It made sense: in a booming economy, everyone would be looking to hire more workers; an increase in demand for labor would lead to an increase in the wage rate. Before long, economists took this relationship even further. Wages weren’t the only thing rising in a booming economy—so were prices in general, pulled along by high demand. The lower the unemployment rate, the higher the rate of inflation. The resulting Phillips Curve connecting unemployment and inflation is an observation, not a strict rule. Its key assumption is that there is a natural rate of employment. At the natural rate, the economy is neither depressed nor overheated. Inflation is low, the economy is stable, and children sing and dance. If unemployment is above this natural rate, there is a lot of slack in the economy, and inflation is low. If unemployment is below this natural rate, the economy is overheating, and inflation is high. Data collected in the 1960s seemed to confirm the Phillips Curve. However, the 1970s ushered in both high inflation and high unemployment. Economists concluded there was no single, enduring natural rate of employment: the Phillips Curve changes depending on the overall economic environment. The 1990s, for example, saw low unemployment and low inflation, and today economists worry that efforts to jumpstart the economy are sparking a surge in inflation without noticeably lowering unemployment. 82 He wasn’t a bird, he was a New Zealander. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 107 Lorenz Curve If all people in a country shared its income equally, any 1% of the population would receive 1% of the income, any 5% would receive 5%, any 25% 25%, and so on. This is true nowhere on Earth. The so-called Lorenz Curve illustrates the inequality of real income distribution. The y-axis Debate it! of the Lorenz curve shows the total amount of Resolved: That inequality is important to economic growth. income earned by the percent of people represented by the x-axis. Look at the graph to the right. The bottom 50% of people earn roughly 20% of total income, while the top 10% earn more than 30% of the total income. The inequality is even starker when we measure accumulated wealth rather than income. The poor spend just about all their income, whereas richer people are able to save and invest. The Gini coefficient measures the difference between a line of perfect equality and the real Lorenz curve in an economy. It can be measured as the area of the region titled A. The lower the coefficient, the more equality in the economy. Gini coefficients generally range between about 0.24 in very equal countries such as Denmark to about 0.71 in developing economies with great inequality. The United States is in the middle, at about 0.41. Laffer Curve All else held equal, increasing taxes will result in somewhat less economic activity, since taxes reduce the marginal benefit of economic activity. But, at low tax rates, an increase will not affect overall economic activity very much and will collect significantly more revenue for the government. If doubling the rate from 1% to 2% only slightly reduces the amount of economic activity, overall tax revenue collected will still be much greater. At some point, too high a tax rate is too high, it stifles the economy, and increasing it further leads to a drop in tax revenue. The Laffer Curve shows this relationship between tax rate and total tax revenue collected. It illustrates three important theoretical points. At 0% taxation, no tax revenue is collected. At 100% taxation, no tax revenue is collected. No economic activity takes place; there is no incentive to work. There is some tax rate—at the top of the curve—that maximizes revenue. No one knows what this rate is, and it probably varies by country and by culture. Learn More Online It’s easy to complain about taxes, but it’s worth considering where your country stands relative to the rest of the world. Check out this list of the six countries with the highest and the six countries with the lowest tax rates. Such lists vary by how you measure tax rates, but, in general, you’ll find that the United States has among the world’s lowest tax rates, and the Nordic welfare states, such as Norway, have among the highest: http://tinyurl.com/lowtaxcountries. Unlike a firm seeking profits, maximizing tax revenue is not the typical goal of a government. Most governments balance keeping taxes low enough to encourage economic activity and high enough to fund important programs—such as education. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 108 Say’s Law A factory hires workers and pays them wages. The wages allow the workers to demand and buy other goods.83 Without the factory, the workers would have no money with which to buy things. The French economist Jean Baptiste-Say (1767-1832) first noticed this relationship and stated it as what we now call Say’s Law: that supply creates its own demand. That is, the revenues earned by those producing goods and services are used to buy goods and services—including those they just produced!84 Because of its emphasis on supply as the only real form of wealth, Say’s Law goes against the notion that a recession can be cured by pumping more money into the hands of consumers to stimulate aggregate demand. Say can be thought of as one of the first critics of Keynesian economics85. But Say was not a monetarist either. He believed in monetary neutrality—that the size of the money supply has no effect on an economy and only real wealth, composed of goods and services, matters. Think of Say’s Law as trying to answer the economic chicken-and-egg problem: does demand spur supply or does supply spur demand? Say’s Law implies that employers and entrepreneurs are more important to economic prosperity than typical workers—because they pay out the wages workers need to demand anything at all. They also help control what consumers demand in the first place. Steve Job’s creativity and Apple engineers supplied the iPhone, which people then demanded. One movement associated with Say’s Law is supply-side economics, famously championed by President Ronald Reagan in the 1980s. Reagan, as a champion of the Republican Party, favored tax cuts for businesses, shareholders and investors. His economic team believed these parties would use the tax savings to hire more workers and increase output. Its critics call this approach trickle-down economics, arguing it takes a long time for the benefits to “trickle down” from those enjoying the tax cuts to the average person in the economy. Take note: just as President Jimmy Carter never gave a speech in which he declared America to be in an economic malaise, President Ronald Reagan never referred to his tax policy as trickle-down. These memorable labels were crafted by their opponents. Recently, President Obama began referring to his administration’s health care reform law as “Obamacare”—in so doing, he was owning the derogatory term originally used for it by his political adversaries. 83 Henry Ford followed this principle: he paid his workers enough so they could afford to buy their own Fords. This process is sometimes helped along with employee discounts. 85 He had to have been one of the first, since he died in 1832, 51 years before Keynes was born. 84 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 109 V. Trade and Globalization The world used to be a larger place. When your classmates left to study abroad, that was pretty much the last you heard from them until they came home. Maybe they would send a letter, or make an expensive phone call to a significant other, but mostly, they were gone. There was no e-mail, no Twitter, no sharing of photos on Facebook. Now, people who go abroad can stay in touch very easily. Internet cafes abound. Skype has made phone calls cheap. Men stand on the street corners of La Paz renting cell phones by the minute to anyone who doesn’t already have one. If you ever need to go home in a hurry, you can buy a ticket online and be nearly anywhere within 24 hours.86 In short, distance isn’t what it used to be. Global transportation, communication, and financial interactions are within reach of most middle-class people anywhere on the planet. A Chinese immigrant in New York can order illegal pharmaceuticals from India and have them arrive in a few days. A South African track star in Beijing can have lunch at Burger King and then stroll down to the Gucci shop for a new (increasingly obsolete) timepiece. The world is becoming, in the words of New York Times columnist Thomas Friedman, increasingly flat (and hot and crowded). With this bridging of distance, the role of each country in the global economy is ever more important— and the flow of information, including culture, has come to matter as much as the transport of goods. We will begin this chapter by analyzing why trade is almost always beneficial to countries. We will then move on to questions of development—why countries have turned out the way they have. The two areas combine in a brief look at the economics of imperialism. Relative Price and Comparative Advantage Economists tend to object to trade barriers. Most advocate free trade, trade without barriers, because, in theory, letting the markets freely work their magic should increase the consumption possibilities for everyone. To understand why trade is so beneficial, you must first understand the law of comparative advantage—which hinges on the concept of relative price. To determine which goods to produce and which goods to import, a country has to examine its production possibilities and determine which goods it can produce at the lowest opportunity cost. The relative price of a good is the cost of producing it, expressed in terms of an alternative good. In 86 Unless you’ve been arrested by the Iranian government. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 110 other words, the relative price of a good is the opportunity cost of producing one more unit of it— expressed in terms of the alternative good. To determine a country’s relative price for one good, we divide the total number of units of the other good the country can produce with a given amount of resources by the total number of units of the first good that can be produced with the same resources. Relative Price of Good A = Total Possible Units of Good B Total Possible Units of Good A Relative Price of Good B = Total Possible Units of Good A Total Possible Units of Good B The relative price of good X, relative to Y, is expressed in the form of “units of Y per unit of X.” For instance: “three bushels of wheat per pair of shoes.” Suppose we can somehow combine all the resources available in a country (land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurship) into generic “units” of resources. In the country of Decalon, one of these units can produce 10 missiles. It can also produce 20 gallons of milk (but no missiles). And of course, one unit could be used to produce some mix of missiles and milk. To produce a missile, Decalon must give up two gallons of milk. The relative price of one missile is 2 gallons of milk—and the relative price of milk is ½ missiles per gallon. To produce another gallon of milk, the country must trade off half a missile. Relative Price of a Missile = 20 Gallons of Milk 10 Missiles = 2 Gallons per Missile Relative Price of a Gallon of Milk = 10 Missiles 20 Gallons of Milk = ½ Missile per Gallon The Production Possibilities Frontier earlier in this guide represented this trade-off between two goods. The PPF for Decalon can help us to visualize the relative prices of milk and missiles. The relative price of a missile is two gallons of milk, so if Decalon wants one more missile, it must sacrifice two gallons of milk. It must move along the frontier. If Decalon wants to produce one more gallon of milk, then it must be willing to sacrifice half a missile—another movement along the frontier. The relative price of a good is important when we compare it with the relative price of the same good in another country. From one country to the next, the relative price of a good will differ—since each has different resources. When the relative price of a good is different in two countries, they should probably be trading. If a country can produce a good for a lower relative price than another country, it has a comparative advantage in the production of that good. The law of comparative advantage holds that whenever two countries can produce the same goods at different relative prices, the two countries can benefit from trade—each trading the good for which it has a lower relative price. This law was first devised by the economist David Ricardo. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 111 We can use this approach to expand on the example of Decalon. This time we add a second country, Demilon, to see how each country can leverage its comparative advantage to determine how to trade. The table below provides information about the production possibilities in each country: Production Possibilities in Demilon and Decalon Country Missiles Produced with Gallons of Milk Produced with One Unit of Resources One Unit of Resources Decalon 10 20 Demilon 20 200 From the data, we can find the relative prices of a missile and a gallon of milk in each country. Relative Prices Of Missiles and Milk in Demilon and Decalon Country Relative Price of One Missile Relative Price of One Gallon of Milk Decalon 2 Gallons of Milk 1/2 Missile Demilon 10 Gallons of Milk 1/10 Missile It would seem Demilon has no need to trade; it can produce milk and missiles more efficiently than Decalon. But Decalon can produce missiles for the lower relative price: two gallons of milk. Demilon can produce a gallon of milk for the lower relative price: one tenth of a missile. According to the law of comparative advantage, this means Decalon should produce and export missiles and Demilon should produce and export milk. Suppose Decalon produces The Effect Of Trade in Demilon and Decalon (Hypothetical) only missiles, all 10 of them. In turn, Demilon produces Country Production Possibility Before Trade Consumption Possibility After Trade 200 gallons of milk, and the Decalon 5 Missiles and 10 Gallons of Milk 5 Missiles and 40 Gallons of Milk two countries agree to trade Demilon 5 Missiles and 150 Gallons of Milk 5 Missiles and 160 Gallons of Milk milk for missiles at a rate of 8 gallons per missile (or 1/4 missile per gallon). If Decalon traded all 10 of its missiles, it could buy 80 gallons of milk from Demilon. If Demilon traded all 200 of its gallons, it could buy 25 missiles, in theory, but Decalon cannot quite produce that many. Suppose Demilon trades only 40 of its gallons of milk. The country buys 5 missiles and keeps 160 gallons of milk. Decalon sells 5 missiles for 40 gallons, and keeps the other 5 missiles. Without trade, Demilon could only have had 5 missiles and 150 gallons of milk, and Decalon 5 missiles and 10 gallons of milk. With trade, Demilon gains 10 more gallons of milk and Decalon 30 more gallons. Absolute Advantage As we saw with the farmwives’ cooperative on the prairie, some people are just plain better at making certain things than other people are. This is true of whole countries, too. Some are more efficient at producing cars. Others are better at making cheese. When one country can produce more of a particular good than another country, it has an absolute advantage in its production. In other words, if one country can produce a good with fewer resources than it takes another country to produce the same good, it has an absolute advantage in the production of that good. (Remember that it may not have a comparative advantage even if it has an absolute advantage.) ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 112 Below, you’ll see hypothetical data about the production possibilities in two countries. Given 100 hours of labor, France can produce 20 quarts of ice cream or 20 boxes of waffle cones. Using the same 100 hours of labor, England can produce 33 quarts of ice cream or 10 boxes of waffle cones. England has an absolute advantage in the production of ice cream because the country can produce ice cream more efficiently than France. On the other hand, France can produce more waffle cones in the same 100 hours; France thus has an absolute advantage at waffle-cone-making. Production Possibilities in France and England One View of Absolute Advantage Country Quarts of Ice Cream Produced Boxes of Waffle Cones Produced with 100 Labor Hours with 100 Labor Hours France 20 20 England 33 10 In the next table, we will see the same data differently. The table below indicates how many hours of labor are needed to produce a quart of ice cream or a box of waffle cones in either country. Again, we see that England has an absolute advantage over France in making ice cream because it can produce a quart of ice cream in fewer labor hours than France. Meanwhile, France has an absolute advantage in making waffle cones because it can produce a box of waffle cones in fewer labor hours than England. Production Possibilities in France and England Country Hours Needed to Produce a Hours Needed to Produce a Quart of Ice Cream Box of Waffle Cones France 5 5 England 3 10 Regardless of how you choose to see it, an absolute advantage means one country is more efficient than another in the production of a particular good. You can say that, given the same amount of resources, a country can produce more of one good than another so it is more efficient. Alternatively, you can say a country is more efficient because it uses fewer resources to produce a particular good. An absolute advantage is not a sufficient reason to trade. A country should only trade when it has a comparative advantage in the production of a good. In fact, we can build on the law of comparative advantage now. Regardless of its absolute advantages or disadvantages, if a country has a comparative advantage in the production of some good, the country should produce and export that good. Exchange Rates An exchange rate is the price of the currency in one country, expressed in terms of the currency in another country. If you need two dollars to buy one euro, then the exchange rate of the dollar against the euro is two dollars per euro, or one-half euro per dollar. We use exchange rates to determine Debate it! the price of goods in terms of foreign Resolved: That currencies should have fixed exchange rates. currency. Suppose a pair of French shoes costs €50 and one euro is worth two U.S. dollars. An American would need $100 to buy that pair of shoes. Now suppose the exchange rate changed: now it takes $2.50 to buy one euro. An American ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 113 would need $125 to buy the same pair of shoes. Even though the quality of the shoes has not improved, and nothing has happened to the supply of shoes, an American has to pay more for the same pair of shoes simply because the exchange rate has changed. When the price of one country’s currency increases relative to the price of another country’s currency, the first country’s currency is said to appreciate against the currency of the second. When the price of one country’s currency decreases, relative to the price of another country’s currency, the first country’s currency is said to depreciate against the currency in the second. Holding all else constant, an appreciation of one country’s currency will make its goods more expensive to foreigners. Today, most exchange rates are allowed to float: they change based on market forces. A few are still pegged, or fixed at certain values relative to another currency. For many years, the value of one Chinese yuan was pegged at .132 United States dollars—a ratio that kept Chinese goods artificially “cheap” in dollar terms and helped lead to a continuing trade imbalance. In 2005, bowing to international pressure, the Chinese government allowed the yuan to begin floating, but it has limited the range of possible values. At the time of writing, the exchange rate is 0.143 yuan to the dollar. Economic Development Thresholds and Trends We can divide countries into developed Debate it! countries, developing countries, and lessResolved: That only less developed countries willing to limit developed countries (LDCs). These population growth should receive international aid. classifications typically use GDP per capita. Countries in which GDP per capita is under $3,000 are “less-developed”; countries in which it ranges from $3,000 and $10,000 are “developing”; and countries in which it is above $10,000 are “developed.” There are drawbacks to such arbitrary classifications. GDP per capita is just average GDP per person, so it reveals nothing about income distribution. Poor countries often have a privileged few who are very wealthy; those few might make enough to overstate “average” wealth. The Gini coefficient of a country can help make sense of this. GDP per capita Status Population Examples < $3,000 Less-developed country (LDC) ‘‘Third World’’ High growth rate due to high fertility. Many young people. Pakistan, Guatemala, India, many African nations such as Nigeria, Egypt and Uganda $3,000-$10,000 Developing country Varies greatly. Many Latin American nations, Asian countries such as Thailand and China, some former Soviet republics > $10,000 Developed country ‘‘First World’’ Low or slightly negative growth rate. U.S., Taiwan, Canada, Australia, United Arab Emirates, Japan, South Korea, most of Europe Why is this Country Different from All Other Countries? Walk the streets of Brisbane and you may find yourself mesmerized by the clean lines and prosperous look of the city and its inhabitants. Hike the outskirts of Kathmandu and hungry, undressed children will run after you pleading for spare change—and then return to crooked houses with broken roofs. Most of the world’s developed countries are in North America, Europe, Asia, and Australia. Its less developed countries are clustered in Asia and Africa. Researchers have spent considerable effort trying to ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 114 decipher why some countries have developed more than others. Some factors may simply be an accident of history: if Haiti, for example, had not been turned into a slave colony, perhaps it would have found greater success in the global economy. Others may be a function of climate and geography: it is simply harder to build a thriving civilization in the swamp, or when a third of the population is always sick with malaria. Developed countries tend to be industrialized and rely less on agriculture and basic manufacturing. In other words, Singapore makes motherboards—and Thailand makes textiles. They also depend less on foreign aid and investment. Their people enjoy better health; they tend to have more education, lower birth rates, and longer life expectancies. Most developed countries have older populations that are growing less quickly, or even shrinking87—while less developed countries have high population growth rates despite higher shorter life expectancies and greater infant mortality. Nations vary in their average labor productivity—how each person in their workforce contributes to GDP. The average worker in more developed countries tends to be more productive than the average worker in less developed countries. This difference results from a number of factors; studying them can help less developed countries determine how to focus their economic development. More developed countries tend to have more physical capital: better roads, newer factories, more computers, faster Internet, etc. They also benefit The Bretton Woods system from superior human capital: a healthier and Named for the New Hampshire town where world more educated workforce. They often have more leaders met to plan the world’s economic future in natural resources—such as forests, mines, oil 1944, the Bretton Woods system aimed to prevent a reserves, and natural harbors. Their workforce repeat of the financial chaos of the Great Depression also has access to better technology—from by ensuring, among other things, that all countries fixed the value of their currencies to the price of vaccines to high speed Internet. Institutions also gold. In return, participating countries could enjoy make a tremendous difference. In countries with funding from the IMF in times of crisis or economic effective courts and rule of law—where banks shortfall. Bretton Woods was widely accepted in the function predictably and the police are there to West until 1971, when U.S. President Nixon suddenly announced the United States would no longer tie the protect you, not demand bribes—business and value of its currency to gold. The system collapsed. entrepreneurship can flourish, maximizing everyone’s productive potential. Economic Development Organizations The period immediately following World War II was a busy time for economic planners—as war-torn Europe sought to rebuild and governments lingered over the lessons of the Great Depression. In general, the Western powers (excluding the Soviet Union) believed in a post-war world driven by capitalist markets. But their experience with the Great Depression also led them to support government intervention and international cooperation to prevent undue hardship and instability. In July 1944, as World War II was ending, economists and diplomats from 44 nations met in Bretton Woods, a town in New Hampshire. Their mission was to plan the post-war economy. One notable participant was John Maynard Keynes. Though most famous for his theories on fiscal policy and deficit spending, Keynes first gained notoriety when he wrote a book criticizing the terms of the Versailles 87 In fact, the population of the United States would be declining if not for immigration. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 115 Treaty that ended World War I. He had served as a (largely unheeded) participant at the talks that designed that treaty—and here he had another chance to shape a post-war world. Among other things, the Conference designed two institutions: the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD). The IBRD later evolved into the World Bank. The IMF and the World Bank are administered in similar ways. Both are associated with the United Nations, but each is self-governed. Both currently have 185 member states. Both are funded by their member states and based in Washington, DC. The IMF levies a set quota from each member state, while the World Bank sells subscriptions. These contributions are roughly proportional to the size of a nation’s economy. As the largest shareholders of both organizations, the United States and European countries have the most say in their policies. By unwritten convention, the president of the World Bank is always an American and the managing director of the IMF a European. International Monetary Fund (IMF) The IMF was founded to help restore and maintain the stability of the international monetary system, helping its member states at times of economic instability. Its stated goals are to achieve “global prosperity” through: the balanced expansion of world trade stability of exchange rates avoidance of competitive devaluations correction of balance of payments issues To fulfill these goals, the IMF monitors the world economy and the economies of individual member countries. It provides advice and warnings. It also lends to members facing balance of payment problems. These are nations that face a shortage of reserves to pay their international obligations. Think of it as the global equivalent of the stern parents coming in to rescue a child from credit card debt. The parents might help to pay off the debt, but will probably make their child adopt different habits, submit future credit card statements to them for examination, and pay them back over time. The IMF does something similar on a national and international level. The conditions imposed by the IMF are often structural adjustments that include reforms to economic and political structures. These may include anti-corruption measures and deregulation of the banking sector. The IMF also often recommends currency devaluation, since many balance of payment problems are caused by overvalued currency. The IMF also provides technical assistance to the governments and central banks of its member countries. This often includes sending experts to work on projects related to a member’s economy. The IMF’s performance has historically been mixed; it has critics on all sides of the political spectrum. Many complaints center on its austerity programs, which it imposes on nations in financial distress. These programs try to improve the budget situation by raising taxes and reducing government spending. This can lead, short-term, to a worsening of the economy for consumers. IMF supporters point out the IMF can only respond to problems, not prevent them. Thus, the IMF often comes into a situation after a long period of pre-existing mismanagement, and there are no easy fixes. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 116 The World Bank The World Bank is similar to any other bank.88 It loans money to development projects around the world at low rates of interest. For the most part, it collects on those loans. When it was first created, its primary mission was financing the reconstruction of war-torn Europe. Today, its primary goal is poverty alleviation and development projects, mostly in the Third World. Like a brick and mortar bank89, the World Bank Group is owned by someone. Its shares are held by its member nations, which provide the funds to sponsor the bank’s activities. The World Bank is not meant as a giveaway fund. Most of its disbursements are loans that need to be repaid. In this way, the World Bank is largely self-financed. However, it does also give grants that do not have to be repaid.90 The most typical criticism of the World Bank is that it promotes policies that benefit the wealthy nations that control it. It is true that many of its loans come with strings attached, such as requiring the structural adjustments also pursued by the IMF—and that many of these structural adjustments include deregulation, which may help Western multinational corporations enter new markets. These criticisms often go hand-in-hand with criticisms of unfettered free trade. Some allege, for instance, that World Bank funds are spent to bail out private investors—mostly wealthy individuals from wealthy countries—from bad loans that they should never have given. The Gold Standard Bretton Woods also laid out the rules for a Debate it! new, more stable world monetary system Resolved: That currencies should have fixed exchange rates. centered on the United States dollar. Most major currencies were more or less pegged to the dollar. For its part, the dollar was backed up by the United States’ gold reserves at a fixed exchange rate of 35 dollars per ounce of gold. (One dollar was worth one-thirty-fifth of an ounce of gold.) For a while, the system worked well, since most of the other wealthy nations of the world were indebted to the United States after the war. The United States had become the wealthiest and most productive nation in the world by far. It had the majority of the world’s gold reserves and produced most of the world’s coal, oil and industrial goods. It was also the world’s largest creditor. The system broke down in later years. The global economy’s rapid growth outpaced the United States’ reserve of gold and the United States became a debtor nation as its trade surplus turned into a trade deficit and its government spending soared. In 1971, President Richard Nixon pulled the United States off the gold standard, formally ending the original Bretton Woods system. The Bretton Woods institutions, however, are still alive and strong, and worldwide faith in the stability of the United States91 maintains the value of the dollar.92 88 In the United States, that now implies it gives bad mortgage loans and could shut down at any time. But without free online checking. 90 Think of it as a college financial aid office for the world. 91 This faith took a hit in 2008, however, and has not quite recovered. 92 Tell that to the next American who visits London and discovers a latte costs $7. 89 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 117 Selected International Organizations Organization Description HQ and Head Members World Bank (formerly the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development) Conceived at Bretton Woods. Made first loan in 1947 to France for post-war reconstruction. Currently makes loans to LDCs for economic development. Washington D.C. President Robert B. Zoellick (U.S.) 184. All UN members participate in some way except North Korea, Cuba, Monaco, Tuvalu, Liechtenstein, Andorra, and Nauru International Monetary Fund (IMF) Conceived at Bretton Woods. Protects international monetary stability by giving advice and making loans to governments with currency and debt crisis. Washington D.C. Managing Director Dominique StraussKahn (France) 184 (same members as World Bank) Bank for International Settlements (BIS) 1930: Founded with Hague agreements. Its mission is to work with central banks to foster monetary and accounting stability. Basel, Switzerland General Manager Jaime Caruana (Spain) 55 member central banks G20 (recently assumed most of the G8’s responsibilities) Holds annual summits among leading policymakers (often heads of states). World Scholar’s Cup (WSC) Promotes alpacas as the international animal of learning. Holds tournaments for students from around the world. United States Daniel Berdichevsky About 30 countries, and increasing each year. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) Established in 1948 to help administer the Marshall Plan in post-war Europe. Provides data and a forum to promote free markets. Paris Secretary-General Jose Angel Gurría (Mexico) 30-----all members are industrialized, wealthy countries with representative governments and market-driven economies Includes 20 leading economies. The European Union counts as one economy. The Rise of GATT and the WTO At the start of the Great Depression, Americans began to worry about imports taking American jobs. In response, despite the cautions of countless economists, Congress passed the Smoot-Hawley Tariff of 1930. It dramatically raised import duties. Other countries reciprocated. Like the individual decisions to withdraw bank savings following the stock market crash, raising tariffs was the sort of reaction that seemed to make sense for each country on its own. But when everyone did it, disaster followed. Soon international trade had plummeted by 58 percent. The decline did not help already hurting economies worldwide. The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) was launched in 1947 to prevent these sorts of reckless and uncoordinated trade restrictions. GATT was a regular conference of countries meeting to discuss and work together to reduce barriers on trade. It helped shape and coordinate the rules. It could not, however, enforce them. Increased trade creates enormously complicated issues of legality and fairness. When products and capital can travel around the world, any country in which they make a pit stop is affected by them. Is it acceptable for a country to charge any sort of fee on goods that cross its borders? Do the laws of one country always apply to goods imported from another? Can items be manufactured in countries without strong labor and safety regulations, then sold to more-regulated countries? These questions were generally settled by treaties between individual countries; after 1947, GATT brought many of these countries together in collective treaties, but no single organization had the power to enforce trade rules globally. Hence the creation of the World Trade Organization (or WTO), an international governing body that manages the rules and practices of world trade. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 118 Based in Geneva, the WTO grew out of GATT in the early 1990s. In addition to providing a GATTlike forum for the development of trade policy, the WTO has another important function: it settles disputes. When two or more countries disagree over a trade issue, the arguments can be extraordinarily bitter, since the issue often has profound implications for each country’s economic health. Sometimes these debates can even lead to war. The WTO thus has sweeping powers to judge these arguments on their merits and issue decisions. Disputes brought before the WTO are administered by the Dispute Settlement Body (DSB), which has the power to investigate problems, issue reports and judgments, and then monitor compliance with its rulings. Rulings can be appealed to an Appellate Body, a three-person panel chosen from a pool of seven. When necessary, the WTO’s decisions can be enforced through the temporary raising of tariff barriers or the imposition of other penalties (although some powerful economies, such as the United States or European Union, have at times simply ignored WTO decisions against them). The idea at the heart of the WTO is that nations and businesses are best served when they can freely trade goods and services. The WTO enforces a policy called the Most Favored Nation (MFN) rule: it requires any WTO member to treat all its trading partners (or at least those which have MFN status, as determined by the WTO) the same way it treats its best trading partner. In other words, the United States could not offer a sweetheart deal on lumber imports to its neighbor Canada without offering the same terms on lumber to every other “most favored” trading partner. (Developing countries are exempt from the MFN rule.) Not everyone agrees with the WTO’s mission, or with the idea that free trade helps reduce poverty and promotes healthy economic growth. A few economists and many activists link rising inequality around the world to free trade, arguing that the unfettered flow of resources out of developing countries tends to bleed those countries dry while enriching the wealthy few who operate international businesses. Others blame free trade for the loss of good jobs in developed countries and the persistence of low wages and poor working conditions in developing countries. Since free trade allows multinational businesses to produce goods anywhere, they naturally move production to countries where production is cheapest—even if this means hiring workers for very little pay or endangering the environment. Labor activists call this phenomenon the race to the bottom. But the WTO is not going away any time soon. The vast majority of economists agree that free trade, in the long term, is good for everyone. The developed countries, where most multinational corporations are based, certainly have no incentive to pull out. Today’s globalized economy depends in numerous ways on free trade continuing to flow, for better or worse. WTO members must commit to Debate it! follow its policies, which are agreed on Free trade should be limited in order to safeguard different cultures. at in-depth, multi-year meetings called “rounds.” The first formative talks for the WTO were the Uruguay Round in 1993. Most GATT and WTO rounds have concluded by lowering or eliminating tariffs on specific goods; the current Doha round (named for its location in Qatar93) has been ongoing since 2001 and is mired in controversy over a number of issues. For example, negotiations broke off at one point because the United States, India and China could not agree on special tariffs to protect poor farmers. 93 Which is, incidentally, where I am editing this guide. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 119 As of 2010, the WTO had 153 members. The largest economy not in the WTO (yet) is Russia. Trade Blocs and Free Trade Associations A trade bloc is a group of nations that has a special trade agreement. A free trade association (FTA) is a trade bloc94 with free internal trade that may enact barriers against trade with non-members. Debate it! Resolved: That countries should only be allowed to join one free trade zone. Europe has the world’s single most powerful trade bloc, the European Union (EU)—formed by the 1992 Maastricht Treaty. More than a free trade association, the European Union is a step along the path toward the political and economic unification of Europe. It now includes 27 member countries. Because of the lack of trade barriers and its unified currency, the euro, the EU is now seen as a single economy roughly on par with the American economy. The EU’s political power has grown over the years, to a wary reception among many Europeans. It now has a presidency rotated among its member states, carries out foreign relations, and has a court of human rights whose decisions are binding on member states. It is based on Brussels, Belgium, where the EU parliament meets. It has also been expanding into the former Communist countries of Eastern Europe and the Balkans. All EU member states must meet certain political, economic, and human rights standards, and any new members must be approved by all existing members. In 1992, the United States, Canada and Mexico signed the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). NAFTA went into effect on January 1st, 1994. Although all barriers to trade are not yet gone among the three NAFTA countries, they are being gradually reduced. The Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) was an agreement to build a free trade zone among all the countries of North and South America except Cuba. It was scheduled to be enacted by 2005 but is now in limbo. In South America, a number of nations have united in a free-trade zone called Mercosur. Full members are Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay and Argentina; neighboring Chile and Bolivia are associate members. The Andean Community of Nations (formerly the Andean Pact) is a parallel free trade area between the mountainous countries of Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, and Venezuela. In Africa, the Common Market for Southern and Eastern Africa (COMESA) has brought together 21 nations to create a free trade area; like the FTAA, it is still in the process of development. In Asia, Brunei, Indonesia, Malaysia, Singapore, Thailand, Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar, Vietnam, and the Philippines are part of ASEAN: the Association of Southeast Asian Nations. The island nations of the South Pacific, the Cook Islands, Fiji, Kiribati, Nauru, Niue, Palau, Papua New Guinea, Samoa95, Solomon Islands, Tonga, Tuvalu, and Vanuatu, have formed PICTA: the Pacific Island Countries Trade Agreement. You won’t be tested on this, but it can be fun to learn these country names and mention them randomly at parties. 94 Interesting how trade blocs ware made to stop trade blocks. A friend of mine nearly died of eating rotten ketchup in Samoa. This problem arises when restaurants use glass bottles, because no one wants to eat the ketchup at the bottom; it just sits there menacingly. 95 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 120 Opposition to Globalization and Free Trade Some people are very opposed to globalization and free trade. They do not like the dominance of global (often American) products, ideas, popular culture and business practices. Others worry about low quality goods infiltrating their economies from countries with less quality control. For example, Chinese toys, kimchi, and milk have all been, at times, found to be dangerous, as has American beef. Proponents want free trade to be safe trade, but with such a large global economy, some problems do slip through the cracks.96 Why is this news? Because the last time Korea imported A frequent complaint is that free trade agreements kimchi from China, it turned out to be infested with parasites. favor businesses and production at the expense of human rights, equality, and the environment. Critics argue that, around the world, family-owned businesses, small farms, and local firms are being driven out by giant chains (such as Wal-Mart and Carrefour) and corporations. These businesses have fewer ties to communities and, it can be argued, view the world as a large market from which to make profit. Driving free trade are leaders of countries and companies who want a flexible world in which they can optimize production by marshaling resources more freely—and consumers who want high quality products and services at the lowest possible prices. Companies scour the world for the lowest production costs, starting a factory in one country only to shut it down after finding even cheaper production elsewhere. Workers in developed countries may feel betrayed when investors and business leaders move their jobs abroad. In developed countries, wages in industries such as manufacturing are converging towards global standards (usually lower). Meanwhile, wages in developing countries are also converging toward those standards—making, for example, call centers in India less cost-effective for American companies than they were ten years ago. A 1999 WTO summit in Seattle met with over 30,000 protesters, and a 2003 meeting in Cancun collapsed when developing countries objected to subsidies for farmers in the developed world. In the United States, the most memorable political showdown over free trade occurred in the 1992 presidential election, when third-party candidate Ross Perot took a hard line against NAFTA. He claimed it would lead to a “giant sucking sound” as American companies opened up factories in Mexico, 96 Even the mechanisms of trade are subject to concern. For example, truck drivers from Mexico are seen as a threat on America highways because their vehicles do not meet certain standards. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 121 where they could pay lower wages.97 In recent years, the narrow passage of a free trade agreement with Korea in the United States Congress, chaos in the Eurozone, and the election of nationalist leaders in Venezuela and Bolivia have all suggested unease with both economic and cultural globalization. Trade Sanctions Trade sanctions are tariffs, quotas or other Debate it! administrative rules imposed as punishment Resolved: That dumping can be an appropriate business practice. or retaliation against another nation for some behavior that offends the implementing nation. Trade sanctions are often narrow and used only for commercial disputes. Economic sanctions, on the other hand, are imposed for political reasons, such as by the United Nations against Iraq under Saddam Hussein. In 2002, the United States implemented tariffs on imported steel to protect domestic manufacturers from what it claimed to be foreign dumping practices. Dumping occurs when firms sell a lot of a good or service at below market prices, taking a temporary loss to drive competitors out of business. The European Union brought charges against the United States to the WTO, claiming the tariffs were not allowed. In 2003, the WTO ruled in the EU’s favor, and President Bush rescinded the tariffs. More recently, Japan, the EU and Canada implemented tariffs against the United States in retaliation for an American law that gives proceeds of anti-dumping fines to American firms in an impacted industry. The WTO ruled the law to be illegal and the United States promised to repeal it. For its part, the United States has threatened trade sanctions against countries, such as Japan, that routinely ban American beef following discoveries of mad cow disease in North America. The European Union has also banned many genetically modified agricultural products, as well as threatened sanctions over the use of the pesticide DDT. Brazil recently mulled sanctions against the United States for its subsidies to cotton farmers, and it and other Latin American countries are also considering sanctions against China for dumping cheap textiles on them. Important Trade Blocs and Free Trade Agreements Name Dates Countries The EU (European Union) The Maastricht Treaty (signed 1992—effective 1993) created the euro and the modern European Union. Member states must be democratic, respectful of human rights, open to the free market, and willing to follow European Union laws and regulations. Currently 28 members, including nearly all of Western Europe and expanding into Eastern Europe. Notable nonmembers are Norway, Switzerland, Serbia and Russia. NAFTA (North American Free Trade Agreement) Signed 1992-----effective Jan 1, 1994, with an environment and labor side agreement negotiated in 1993 United States, Canada, Mexico ASEAN Free Trade Area (Association of Southeast Asian Nations) Set up by the Singapore Declaration in 1992, specifying tariff reductions through 2008. Came into full effect early, in 2003. Brunei, Vietnam, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Laos, Singapore, Thailand, Cambodia, Myanmar FTAA (Free Trade Area of the Americas) Talks began in 1994, but progress has stalled. All American countries except Cuba Mercosur Began with Treaty of Asunción (signed Mar 26, 1991) and updated by Treaty of Ouro Preto (signed Dec 17, 1994) Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay 97 NAFTA’s impact has been tremendous. Mexican exports jumped from under US$40 billion in 1991 to US$158 billion in 2002 and nearly US$200 million in 2006. Likewise, imports from the United States went from pre-NAFTA levels of US$37 billion in 1991 to US$128 billion in 2000 and US$134 billion in 2006. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 122 Andean Community of Nations (CAN) Began with Cartagena Agreement in 1969. Free trade area took effect in 1993. Amended by later agreements. In 2003, CAN and Mercosur officials discussed plans for free trade between the two trade blocs. Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Venezuela DR-CAFTA (Dominican Republic-Central American Free Trade Agreement) All parties ratified except Costa Rica. Passed US Senate 6/30/2005, passed US House in 7/28/2005. Dominican Republic, Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua (NOT: Haiti, Panama, Belize, Cuba) GATT (obsolete) 1948 Geneva Round: GATT launched 1993 Uruguay Round: Last round of GATT, ushered in the WTO Many countries WTO Jan 1, 1995: Officially replaced GATT 153 countries as of 2010, including China but not Russia formerly the Andean Pact ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 123 V. The Global Economic Crisis On September 15, 2008, India was celebrating Engineer’s Day98, Prince Harry turned a swoon-worthy 24, and Barack Obama was 50 days from being elected president of the United States. It was an active day in the markets, but not an unusual one. Then the roof caved in. That morning99, the fourth largest investment bank in the United States—Lehman Brothers—filed for bankruptcy. It was the largest bankruptcy in American history, and it helped trigger a global economic crisis. Four years later, that crisis continues. In Europe, one country after another has teetered on the brink of financial collapse. The European Central Bank has taken emergency measures to prevent member states of the European Union—and their banks— from defaulting on their debts. Analysts worry that more prosperous countries may begin to abandon the Eurozone rather than risk their own economies to help those countries in worse shape. In the United States, the unemployment rate has been so high for so long that some experts wonder if it reflects a “new normal”— if higher unemployment is here to stay. It peaked at 10% in October 2009, a year after the crisis unfolded, and remains above 8% today. In 2011 one major credit agency downgraded the United States’ debt, meaning it has begun to question whether the United States will ever be able to pay back all the money it has borrowed. You may be studying the Russia economy this year, but you cannot understand where that economy is today without understanding its larger global context since 2008: a context in crisis. The Economy Takes a Bubble Bath Bubbles burst. You know this if you’ve ever blown a bubble, taken a bubble bath, or popped a painful blister101. You would also 98 Vocabulary and Explanation Twenty-seven European countries belong to the European Union (EU); seventeen belong to the Eurozone, meaning they use the Euro as their currency. The European Central Bank coordinates the monetary policy of all EU members. An investment bank is not the sort of bank you would visit to use an ATM100. Investment banks raise and manage enormous sums of money on behalf of individuals, companies, and governments. They are also actively involved in many other financial transactions, including mergers and acquisitions. To default on a debt is to admit you will never pay it back. Imagine: if you borrowed $100 from your friend and never gave it back to him, no one else would want to loan you anything at all, not even a hat. In some countries, when a company realizes it will not be able to pay its debts, it can file for bankruptcy. A bankrupt company doesn’t always go out of business; sometimes it can rework its finances, figure out a way to pay some of its debts, and ‘‘emerge’’ from bankruptcy still operational. The unemployment rate tells us what percentage of the people in a country who are looking for a job can’t find one. A credit agency is an organization that measures how likely someone or something is to pay back its loans. Suppose your school library charged for borrowing books-----and could charge different people different prices. If a credit agency says you are likely to return books on time, the library will probably lend one to you very cheaply, for a few cents a day. But if the agency says you are likely to lose books, the library will probably only lend one to you if you agree to pay a lot for it each day-----so that, if you don’t return it, the library can buy a new copy. The same applies to loans. The better your credit rating, the more cheaply you can borrow money. The price of borrowing money is its interest rate-----if you borrow $100 at a 5% annual interest rate, you will owe $105 after a year. Sadly, it wasn’t Investor’s Day. That kind of irony would be too good to be true, which is why it’s not. At 2 am. Nothing good ever happens at 2 am. 100 Unless you were a country looking to withdraw billions of dollars. 101 Not recommended. 99 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 124 know this if you had been a flower investor in Holland in the 1630s—specifically, a speculator in tulips. Seventeenth century tulips may not seem particularly current as affairs go102, but learning how bubbles work is important to understanding the roots103 of the global economic crisis. Few bubbles were as intense or instructive as the so-called tulipmania of Holland. The first tulips arrived in Holland under the care of the botanist Carolus Clusius in 1593. He planted them in his private garden. His neighbors, however, were struck by their beauty, and at least one stole a bulb so that he could grow his own. The great beauty and diversity of tulips soon inspired the attention—and obsession—of all classes of society104. One tulip was especially coveted: the Semper Augustus, named for a Roman emperor and just as grand. As one historian put it: “Both more prosaic and more sublime than any stock or bond, it was a tulip of extraordinary beauty, its midnightblue petals topped by a band of pure white and accented with crimson flares.” Smart merchants realized there would be high demand for tulips, but limited supply; it can take seven years for a tulip flower to grow from a seed, and bulbs, which sprout more quickly, are hard to produce. These tulip speculators stocked up on tulip bulbs because they believed prices would soar. In 1624, one speculator was offered the equivalent of about $60,000 in today’s dollars for a single tulip bulb—and turned it down to wait for a better offer. Ten years later, Vocabulary and Explanation another man traded his entire farmhouse for three A speculator buys something in order to sell it later at a tulip bulbs. These transactions were not higher price. Speculating is risky, but can be extremely extraordinary. Savvy investors hoped to resell bulbs profitable at the beginning of a bubble. for even more outrageous sums of money than they A bulb is a mini-plant-----almost a pod-----that will grow a new plant and flower immediately. A bulb can split a few were spending on them. times, cloning itself to produce more bulbs, but then is unable to split any further. This makes bulbs highly Then, in the balmy spring of 1637, someone who desirable. had bought a tulip bulb decided he didn’t really want it after all. He didn’t show up to pay for his tulip105. That one failed transaction punctured the bubble. Maybe tulips weren’t worth whole houses after all. Within days the price of tulips had collapsed. Everyone was selling them; no one was buying them. People who had spent princely sums on tulip bulbs were left with no way to salvage their investments. All bubbles follow the same pattern. Smart investors spot an emerging opportunity. They buy up as much as they can. Media, public hysteria, and the arrival of more investors drive the price up and up. 102 Except for landscape artists, gardeners, and confused boyfriends on Valentine’s Day. This is a very weak pun. Call it a punt. 104 Before Angry Birds, there was a lot less to get excited about. 105 This is the sort of thing that happens on eBay all the time. 103 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 125 Then, something happens that makes someone realize there is no real basis for the high prices—and the market collapses. Bubbles are most common in periods of rapid innovation, when new technologies stun us with their new possibilities106. According to The Wall Street Journal, they “may leave us vulnerable to accepting the bizarre rationalizations that often accompany financial speculation.” In other words, new technologies can make us all a little gullible. Consider: when radiation was first discovered, people were so convinced it could cure disease that hundreds of thousands of people bought devices called Revigators to make sure their water was sufficiently radioactive. In the same way, during the dot-com boom of the 1990s, investors were so infatuated with any company related to the shiny new Internet that just adding “.com” to the end of a company’s name could triple its stock price107. Later, as soon as Facebook became popular, investors poured money into other new social networking sites—social networks for dieters108, social networks for car enthusiasts, social networks for pet owners, etc. Most fizzled quickly; it turned out that people didn’t really want to set up ten different profiles109. You’d think we would learn, but bubbles keep happening, from nanotechnology stocks110 to Beanie Babies111. They keep happening because they make economic sense for investors who can “get out” before the market collapses. It is actually in their best interest for a bubble to rise as high as possible. It’s all a matter of timing: buy low, sell high, and watch other people lose their shirts. Vocabulary and Explanation Someone gullible easily falls for things that aren’t true. Try telling someone that alpacas are related to elephants. A gullible person will believe you; a non-gullible person will not. The dot-com boom was a period in the 1990s when Internetrelated companies soared in value. It was not uncommon for a company’s stock to shoot up in value from $15 to $150 per share in a matter of days. A mortgage is a loan ‘‘secured’’ by a piece of property, often a house, called the collateral. That is, if you take a loan from a bank to buy a house, you guarantee that you will pay back the loan-----or else the bank gets your house. A subprime mortgage is one given to a person with bad credit. A subprime mortgage usually charges much higher interest than a normal mortgage. During boom times, banks justify giving these loans for two reasons: because people might have a better chance at paying them back, and because they might be able to ‘‘sell’’ such mortgages to large institutions and investors, handing the risk off at a profit. Collections of mortgages sold by banks are known as mortgage-backed securities. Many economists trace the current global economic crisis to the bursting of the housing bubble in 2006. The bubble had two layers: actual house prices, and the mortgages used to buy those houses. Home prices in the early 2000s were rising across the United States and around the world. Many homeowners discovered they were much better off than they had ever imagined, based just on the 106 This explains apps that allow to use your iPhone as a flashlight and as a voodoo doll. This tactic no longer works, or we’d be the World Scholar’s Cup.Com Foundation. 108 Could social networks for dictators be far behind? 109 Except, presumably, for those with multiple personality disorder. 110 The company Nanometrics, which had nothing to do with nanotechnology, saw its stock price shoot up when eager investors bought up shares by mistake—seduced by their stock symbol, NANO. 111 At one point during the Beanie Baby bubble, some buyers were convinced that they could later resell their Beanie Baby toys for enough money to pay for their children’s college. 107 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 126 increased value of their homes. This new “paper wealth” had a number of consequences, including people spending beyond their means and buying houses they could not afford, on the expectation that they could resell them for more later. Flipping houses—buying houses, remodeling them, and then reselling them for a profit—became so popular that producers even made television shows about it. The house bubble, though, was only part of the real housing bubble. The goods most likely to inspire bubbles are easily tradable, so that they can be passed along from one buyer to the next at higher and higher prices. Stocks, representing partial ownership of a company, are the ultimate example of this: you never hold an actual stock in your hand. Tulips and Tickle-Me Elmos aren’t far behind112. Houses are different. They are big, heavy, and hard to trade113—so investors found a workaround. To take advantage of rising home prices, they began to trade in mortgage-backed securities—essentially, collections of mortgages bundled and sold together. The housing bubble extended beyond the houses themselves to include these much more tradable securities. There are several reasons this led to an economic disaster—simplified and summarized below. Alpaca Farms & Subprime Mortgages Suppose a bank lends you $1,000,000 in a subprime mortgage to help you buy an alpaca farm in the midst of a major alpaca bubble. After two years of paying $500 a month toward the interest on the loan-----$12,000 in all-----you run out of money. ‘‘Sorry,’’ you tell the bank, ‘‘I’m foreclosing the farm.’’ The bank now owns the farm. ‘‘All right,’’ says the bank, ‘‘I’ll just sell it to get back the $988,000 you still owe me.’’ If the alpaca bubble were alive and well, with alpaca farm prices on the rise, the bank could probably sell the farm for $1,100,000. But if the alpaca bubble had burst, the bank might find no one willing to buy the alpaca farm at anything near the original $1,000,000 price. It may end up selling the farm for $600,000-----losing almost half the original loan. Imagine this happening across many loans and many banks, and you’ll understand why the banking sector suffered so much after the housing bubble burst. Worse yet: suppose that instead of keeping the mortgage and taking your payments, the bank had sold the loan to a larger investor. Over 30 years, counting all the interest, you would have paid $2,000,000 for that $1,000,000 loan. Instead of waiting 30 years, however, the bank could sell it for $1,100,000 to someone else. Then, that someone else would collect a profit of $900,000 over 30 years-----but the bank could enjoy $100,000 of profit right away. That larger investor would suffer the consequences if the bubble burst. (1) Like tulip prices, house prices would not go up forever. Someone was eventually going to buy a house that then went down in value. People who ended up owing more for their houses than they were worth were said to be underwater; underwater homeowners were the most likely to give up and default, but so might any homeowner who could no longer afford monthly payments on his loan. (2) Banks offered subprime mortgages to buyers with poor credit. Some were designed so buyers could take them out114 with no money upfront and with very low payments for the first few years—a very tempting proposition! When someone is unable to pay a mortgage, ownership of the house goes to the bank—a process called foreclosure. Banks assumed subprime mortgages were a win-win situation. Either new homeowners would make their payments or they 112 I never want to hold a Beanie Baby in my hand. It can take months to find someone who likes the way you turned the master bedroom into a movie theater. 114 The phrase “take out” is used to describe getting a mortgage. In life you “take out” dinner, dates, and home loans. 113 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 127 would hand over their houses, which, thanks to rising home prices, the banks could then sell for more money than the lost loan. When the housing bubble burst, however, banks were left with foreclosed homes worth less than the original loan. (3) Many banks sold their mortgages to larger institutional investors, bundling them (including the subprime ones) in so-called collateralized debt obligations (CDOs). A form of mortgage-backed securities, CDOs were grouped from least risky to most risky. The different groups were called tranches. (4) Many of the CDOs were still rated by credit agencies, but for their average level of risk. A bundle containing a few very risky subprime mortgages and several less risky mortgages would look like a safe investment—until the subprime mortgages abruptly foreclosed. Over time, mortgage-backed securities were sliced up, traded, and valued in ever more complex ways. As hedge fund strategist David Goodman put it: Institutionalizing the Economy The institutional investors that bought up mortgage-based securities were not just other banks. They included pension funds-----which hold the money that groups of workers are saving for retirement-----and even government-backed agencies, like the strangely-named Fannie Mae. All these institutional investors were at gigantic risk when the bubble burst and the subprime mortgages followed. ‘‘With increasing demand from Wall Street to buy subprime mortgages, banks became motivated to place ever more subprime loans (since they were no longer at risk, should the loans fail), and began to push messages like, ‘‘refinance your home, unlock all that equity, pay off your credit card debt, and go on vacation.’’ Blogger Matt Henderson In September 2008, no one really knew what the liabilities of the system were, or what the value of any of the CDO tranches might be, for there was no market. All the participants in the structured credit market had done their best to hide the degree of leverage in the system … And that is why everything nearly came down. No-one really knew what any of the assets would bring, and who was on the hook for what. Lehman Brothers was one of the most innovative packagers of mortgage-based securities. It even created synthetic CDOs that invested in other CDOs, and guaranteed that if the value of an investment fell more than 20%, it would make up the difference to investors. “This was an act of genius on the part of an obscure profit center in the bowels of the bank,” observes Goodman. Problem was: the damage could not be isolated. The moment one group of CDOs fell more than 20%, so would all the others. When that moment came, institutions and banks began pulling out in a mad rush—and Lehman Brothers fell like a house of cards. Within weeks, the world had lost 50 trillion dollars in value. People’s retirement savings were wiped out; so were entire banks. It was an unprecedented global economic catastrophe—yet it would all have felt very familiar to tulip investors in Holland. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 128 The Great Recession “Let Detroit go bankrupt,” a New York Times editorial advised in November 2008, two months after the government allowed Lehman Brothers to fail. Now the country’s automobile industry was on the edge of collapse. It had long been a symbol of American national pride—but also of inefficiency and mismanagement. Both Presidents Bush and Obama would soon face a choice: allow the car companies to fail, or lend them taxpayer money to keep them in business. The Great Recession115 and Europe’s sovereign debt crisis in Europe have come back again and again to this question: when should governments “bail out” people, companies, and even other governments in need? Mitt Romney is far from the only person to have come out against bailouts. “Should the EU just let Greece fail?” asked David Indiviglio of The Atlantic in 2011. Many answered with an emphatic yes. A German legislator compared Greece to “an alcoholic that you urge to stop drinking and you simultaneously treat to a case of schnapps116.” Opponents of bailouts in the United States use equally passionate language. It’s “time to let underwater homeowners drown,” said investor Marty Boardman in January 2012, criticizing a White House plan to offer those underwater homeowners emergency loans at very low interest rates. When the Bush Administration decided to bail out other struggling banks after the fall of Lehman Brothers, one Congressman, Ron Paul, warned, “What we’re doing today is going to make things much worse.” Like many critics, he argued the free market should be allowed to repair itself— the invisible hand allowed to do its thing. Critics frequently argue that bailouts are unfair to those who have behaved responsibly. Why, they ask, should governments give special help to those who have made bad choices? Defenders of bailouts point out that those receiving them are never given “blank checks” to use however they like. Bailouts come with strict conditions meant to help recipients get their financial houses in order. When President Obama agreed to loan funds to the auto manufacturers, he required they first prove themselves to be on a path to viability. They had to pledge to cut unprofitable 115 116 Many economists began calling it this by 2009, probably because “the Second-Greatest Depression” is difficult to say. Schnapps is an alcoholic beverage popular in Germany. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 129 car models, trim jobs, sell off subsidiaries, and close inefficient factories. When the European Union and International Monetary Fund offered emergency aid to Greece, they insisted the Greek government reduce spending on social programs and pass other austerity measures—measures so draconian117 that they inspired mass protests118. Bailout supporters also argue that they are meant to prevent widespread economic suffering. If a giant bank fails, as Lehman Brothers did, the consequences can affect far more than the owners of that one bank. In the same way, if a single European country were to default on its debt, the financial consequences could spread across Europe and beyond. Vocabulary and Explanation The Recession in America Opening the TARP Door Four years later, Forbes editor Robert Lenzner still wishes the United States government had bailed out Lehman Brothers. “There still would have been negative ramifications in global markets,” he writes, “but maybe not the near collapse of the system. You can relive that near-collapse in this timeline: http://cnnmon.ie/Mw0Db Just one day after the Lehman bankruptcy, the government decided to bail out the giant insurance corporation AIG. Perhaps it had concluded that the collapse of AIG would be too much for the economy to handle. A bailout is a package of aid-----often a mix of loans and grants-----offered to a failing company or organization. The less a government participates119 in an economy, the more it is a free market. No country has a completely free market; different governments participate in their economies in different ways and to different degrees. Something viable is able to survive. You’ll see the term used not just for companies-----‘‘Are its finances viable?’’-----but for plans-----‘‘Is his plan to attend the World Scholar’s Cup viable?’’-----and even political candidates-----‘‘Is the senator’s campaign still viable after his loss in Ohio?’’ When a government severely cuts spending120 to try and get its finances under control, it is undertaking austerity measures. Typical austerity measures include cutting back on social services such as libraries, public education, health care, and welfare. British Prime Minister David Cameron recently declared the United Kingdom must enter an ‘‘age of austerity’’-----in other words, less government spending. Even with AIG on life support, the stock market fell dramatically—and rose—and fell again. It was a period of great volatility. No banks were giving loans, not to individuals and not to one another; the economy was too uncertain. The crisis expanded. By September 25, a nine-day bank run had driven to failure the sixth-largest bank in the United States, Washington Mutual. It was the largest bank failure in American history. Watching all this unfold, Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson championed a massive bailout package: the Troubled Assets Relief Program, or TARP. “The financial security of all Americans ... depends on our ability to restore our financial institutions to a sound footing,” he said. Congress, which had to approve of the plan, was not as convinced. TARP failed the first time it went up for a vote. The Dow Jones, a 117 Draconian is a lovely word for “unusually severe or cruel”. I wouldn’t normally use it, except to give you new insight into the character of Draco Malfoy. 118 It is the music of a people who want their unemployment benefits back. 119 Word choice is so important. I could have written “interferes” here—but it has a less neutral tone than “participates”. 120 In a severely conservative way, of course. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 130 measure of the American stock market, immediately suffered the largest one-day drop ever. On its second try, a Congress passed the law, designating $700 billion for the bailout. One purpose of all that money: for the government to buy back high-risk mortgages and mortgage-backed securities, taking them out of the banking system. Discuss with your team: was TARP a good plan? What measures did it take? How much did it end up costing American taxpayers? “If they’re too big to fail, they’re too big.” Former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan Unpaid in America Unemployment is often the most visible sign of an economic recession. When people lose their jobs, they may not be able to pay for their homes or support their families—and they often turn to the government for help. By 2008, when Lehman Brothers collapsed, unemployment in the United States was already increasing. After taking office in early 2009, President Obama championed a stimulus bill to help improve the economy. The $800 billion “recovery package” included: Over $120 billion for repairing and building new roads, bridges, railroads, and other forms of Vocabulary and Explanation infrastructure A stimulus bill is a law intended to increase economic Over $100 billion for education growth. It usually involves either cutting taxes or creating Over $200 billion in tax cuts more jobs-----both intended to put more money in the hands Over $250 billion in direct help to the poor of consumers. The more money consumers have, the more and unemployed, including food stamps they will buy, and the more they will buy, the more the A nonpartisan agency of the United States government, the Congressional Budget Office, estimates the stimulus bill helped create or save as many as 2.9 million jobs. Many conservative critics disagree. They argue it cost too much and achieved too little—in other words, that it was inefficient. Critics from the other side of the aisle, such as Princeton economics professor Paul Krugman, have the opposite complaint: that the stimulus was too small to make an impact. economy will grow. Someone or something nonpartisan is not politically biased. A non-partisan committee in a country with two political parties might have three members from either party, so that neither side has a majority (over half). Someone on the other side of the aisle has an opposing political view. In many governments, including the United States, different political parties sit in different areas----meaning that there are aisles between their seats. Infrastructure refers to ‘‘stitching’’ that holds an economy together. It includes items such as power lines, highways, train tracks, and, increasingly, high speed Internet. Food stamps are coupons that people can use to buy food. From earlier in this guide, you should recognize that stimulus bills are an example of fiscal policy, in which governments adjust spending or taxes in order to affect the economy. Remember, governments can also implement monetary policy, focused on the money supply. A central bank, such as the Federal Reserve in the United States, can inject more money into the economy or lower interest rates (making it cheaper for people to borrow money from banks). If people borrow more money, they spend more money—and the more they spend, the more the economy grows. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 131 In September 2012, the Federal Reserve announced it would be doing all it could to encourage domestic economic activity—a policy referred to as quantitative easing. Critics have assailed this action as opening the door to inflation. Political Consequences At first, many Americans blamed President Bush, a Republican, for policies—such as less regulation on banks—that critics claimed helped lead to the recession. As a Democrat, Obama won his election easily; his opponent, Republican war hero John McCain, was widely ridiculed for claiming that “the fundamentals of our economy are strong.”121 Voters disagreed. After President Obama took office, his support of the stimulus and of a controversial health care reform bill122 inspired a political backlash in the United States: the tea party movement123. The tea party helped power Obama’s Republican opponents to a major victory in the 2010 midterm elections. Vocabulary and Explanation In the United States, presidents are elected every four years, but national elections are held every two years----which means that, half the time, national elections happen midway through a president’s term. These midway elections are called midterm elections. The tea party is a political movement in the United States that claims to represent the original philosophy of the country’s founders. (American revolutionaries once had a ‘‘tea party’’ in Boston Harbor, throwing British tea into the water to protest British taxation.) Members are generally against taxation, a strong central government, and government spending. Their concern over the national debt-----how much money the government owes-----has become a main topic in American politics. Less regulation for investment banks (and other Wall Street firms) meant that the government allowed banks to take greater risks with their investments-----leading to both great profits and great danger. Public discourse is what people-----the news media, politicians, and other opinion leaders-----are discussing. Sometimes, an important issue is simply not talked about until someone introduces it to the public discourse. Just as the tea party drew attention to the national debt in 2010, a new movement in 2011 tried to refocus the public discourse on inequality. The top 1% of society, it claimed, was wealthier than ever— but the other 99% was worse off. Calling themselves Occupy Wall Street, members of the movement literally camped out in financial centers all over the globe. “We are the 99%!” became one of their most famous chants. They complained that recent American presidents had favored investors and the alreadywealthy over opportunities for the middle and lower classes. As we go to print, Obama is now running for a second term. No American president since World War II has been reelected when the country’s unemployment rate was above 7.2%; Obama is running with an unemployment rate of 8.1%124. Will he defy history?125 By the time you attend competition, you will know the answer to that question—and the next chapter in American economic history will have begun. 121 In his defense, he went on to acknowledge “tremendous turmoil in our financial markets and Wall Street.” Among other things, it required all Americans to purchase health insurance to cover their expenses in the event of illness or injury. Opponents claimed this mandate was unconstitutional, but the Supreme Court approved it in 2012 as a function of the government’s power to tax. The law remains controversial, however, and relatively unpopular. 123 The tea party was also very critical of TARP, but it had been passed under a Republican president. 124 As of September 2012. 125 Arguably, every election defies history in some way or another. 122 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 132 The European Sovereign Debt Crisis Even the Great Depression of the 1930s—which we Americans tend to remember as our own dismal historical episode—had global reach. This new global financial crisis has emerged in an even more interconnected world, and its consequences have touched every continent. Europe, in particular, has been hit hard—and Russia with it. By 2009, several countries in the European Union had levels of debt that deeply worried investors. Credit rating agencies cut their ratings on their national bonds—suggesting they no longer trusted that they would ever be repaid. The Crisis Unfolds Economists are split on why these debts reached a breaking point. Some countries, such as Ireland, were devastated by the end of the housing bubble. As in the United States, many Irish homeowners ended up underwater and the government had to bail out several of its banks. The bank rescue Definitions and Explanations was expensive; it led to Ireland requiring a $113 The Eurozone countries with the shakiest economies are million bailout of its own from the European Union generally seen as Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, and 127 in 2010 . Ireland’s unemployment rate remains Spain-----PIIGS for short. over 14% in early 2012. Other countries were less affected by the bursting of the housing bubble. The economy of Greece, the poster child for the sovereign debt crisis, was doing well in the early 2000s—but behind the scenes the government was running up a deficit on defense and domestic spending. Its tax revenue was also impacted by tax evasion: it was losing as much $40 billion each year to unreported transactions. Worse, when the global economy collapsed, two important parts of the Greek economy, tourism and shipping, suffered badly. Government tax revenues declined sharply, and, since spending did not decline at the same rate, debt levels surged. A poster child is the perfect example of something. Jeremy Lin is the poster child for underappreciated, hardworking athletes turning out to be stars in hiding. If a government spends more than it earns, it is running up a deficit. If someone pays you $1,000 in cash to clean his house126, and you don’t tell the government about it, you are engaging in an unreported transaction. If you reported it, you would have to pay taxes on it. “The choice is simple: Either we press ahead with the road of change, a road that is difficult, or we choose catastrophe.” Greek Prime Minister George Papandreou Imagine if you owed $100,000 on a college loan. If you made $250,000 a year as an investment banker, that wouldn’t be so bad. But if you only made $50,000 as a teacher, you couldn’t pay off the loan in a single year even if you put all your earnings toward it. Worse, you couldn’t do that anyway: you would need some of the $50,000 to pay for housing, food, and iTunes downloads. You’d be in trouble—just like Greece. 126 127 Presumably a very large house. Bailout begets bailout: hello, domino effect. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 133 In 2010 and 2012, Greece turned to the European Union for help. It received bailout packages on the condition it implement austerity measures, including higher taxes and less spending on social services such as health care and benefits for the unemployed. As in Ireland, those measures were unpopular, inspiring protests—some of them drawing over 100,000 demonstrators. By taking money out of the economy, the austerity measures also worsened the recession. Greece is now entering its fifth year with unemployment rates above 25%. As part of the most recent bailout, even private investors in Greek bonds have agreed to give the government’s debt to them a haircut. “If you go in there with the thought of what's fair and what's not fair, it's going to be tough to get things done,” says investor Hans Humes, whose hedge fund agreed to accept back just 24% of what it was owed—a massive 76% haircut. “This is a situation where there was far too much debt for the Greek economy to support. I think within the context, we ended up getting a deal that is workable.” Some policy makers are urging Greece and other troubled countries to leave the Eurozone and reintroduce its own currencies, which would give them more ways to deal with their debt. For example, if Greece had its own currency, the drachma, it could just print enough money to pay off the debt129. But many analysts call that strategy unwise. The investment bank UBS warns it could lead to "hyperinflation, military coups and possible civil war.” Definitions and Explanations When those who hold a country’s debt agree to devalue it-----to accept back less than they are owed-----they are said to give the loan a haircut. The idea is to make it easier for the country to pay back what it can; better that, the theory goes, than for it to collapse entirely and pay back none of it. The recent European bailout packages have included haircuts. When those who hold a debt agree to erase it from the books completely-----that is, never to collect it at all-----they are said to have forgiven the loan128. When an economy experiences hyperinflation, money becomes almost worthless-----what you can buy with $1 today might require $100 next week and $10,000 by the end of the month. During recessions, people make less money—which means that even with higher tax rates a government brings in less revenue130, making it harder to pay down debt. Remember from earlier in this guide that John Maynard Keynes urged governments to spend more to stimulate economies in recession, even if it means going into debt. Many countries, including the United States, followed his advice during the Great Depression, when it seemed the free market could not recover on its own. As Time magazine put it, “His radical idea that governments should spend money they don't have may have saved capitalism.” During the current economic crisis, some countries have implemented Keynesian policies, but others have avoided them because they tend to require the government to borrow money to pay for them— and the interest on the resulting debt could cripple an economy in the future. 128 To err is human; to forgive is expensive. This sounds good until you realize it means that everyone’s money will be worth a lot less. 130 In nearby Italy, the government is trying to increase its tax revenues by requiring consumers to use credit cards instead of cash—since cash income can be more easily hidden from the government. 129 ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 134 All for On€ By 2011, it was clear that certain European countries would require ongoing financial assistance. The 27 members of the European Union collectively formed the European Financial Stabilisation Mechanism (EFSM), an emergency funding institution that could borrow money against a very stable form of collateral: the budget of the European Union itself. In other words, anyone lending money to the EFSM would either get it back or have a claim on the budget of the European Union. In the last year, the EFSM has raised and distributed over 26 billion euros to member countries. Political Consequences In several Eurozone countries, including Portugal, Greece, Spain, and Italy, anger over the bailouts, austerity measures, and stubborn unemployment has led to dramatic elections and changes of leadership. In Italy, Giorgio Napolitano replaced the beleaguered131 Silvio Berlusconi as Prime Minister; in Spain, the more centrist People’s Party took power from the liberal Socialist Workers’ Party. In general, whichever party was in office when the crisis began was likely to lose support. Even outside the Eurozone, in the United Kingdom, David Cameron’s Conservative Party drove Gordon Brown’s Labour Party out of power and implement a more austerity-focused agenda. The crisis has also helped drive people out of countries altogether. In Greece, a government program to help citizens move to Australia had only 42 sign-ups in 2010—but over 12,000 in 2011. Families that can afford it are sending their children to study abroad, where they are more likely to find jobs. Long term, the loss of young talent will harm all the countries affected by the sovereign debt crisis. The crisis has also affected the balance of political power within the Eurozone. Countries whose economies and credit ratings have remained strong, such as Finland, have gained new influence. (Finland was even able to demand nearly a billion euros in collateral from Greece before agreeing to its most recent bailout132.) The Crisis Elsewhere The consequences of the 2008 downturn stretched from abandoned construction sites in Dubai to warehouses in China filling with exports no one abroad could afford to buy. In the face of rising unemployment and failing factories, China passed its own nearly $600 billion stimulus package in November 2008. The Keynesian-style stimulus launched massive infrastructure projects—new roads, high speed trains, and more—that would generate jobs and limit damage from 131 132 Someone beleaguered is being criticized a lot. The word rhymes nicely with leader: be a leader, be beleaguered. Leading to the new saying, you’re not finished without the Finnish. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 135 lost trade. The stimulus cut taxes and spent money on other priorities, such as education and housing. All in all, China’s growth has slowed since 2008, but continued to hover around 9% per year. By comparison, as the global recession took hold, most of the world’s developed economies actually shrank. In Dubai, the collapse of the real estate market hit hard. A massive wave of construction during peak economic times had left empty homes and offices surrounding the city. Dubai’s dependence on global trade also meant that, as the world economy ground to a halt, so did Dubai’s opportunity to play a role on it. Before long, Dubai needed its own $20 billion bailout from the neighboring emirate Abu Dhabi. Foreign workers fled for home, and many extravagant projects—such as a giant glow-in-the-dark pyramid to mirror those in Egypt—were set aside. In regions that depended heavily on manufactured exports, such as Southeast Asia, the downturn increased unemployment and slowed growth. The more connected a country to the global economy, the more it was affected. In Russia, the crisis meant more than a collapse in the price of oil on which the Russian economy vitally depended. In the words of one expert, Stephen Sestanovich of the Council on Foreign Relations: “Russia is confronting virtually all the negatives at once--sharply declining export earnings from energy and metals, over-leveraged corporate balance sheets and a chorus of bailout appeals, a credit crunch and banking failures, a bursting real-estate bubble and mortgage defaults, accelerating capital flight, and unavoidable pressures for devaluation.” By November 2008, Sestanovich had correctly predicted that the expanding crisis in Russia would boost Vladimir Putin’s chances of returning to the presidency—with increased authoritarian trappings and with a growing degree of anti-Western rhetoric133. Just as physics informs the messier natural sciences of chemistry and biology, economics can inform the messiest social science of all: politics. 133 A cynic might observe that a country in trouble needs a strong leader and scapegoats to blame, or it tends to fall apart. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 136 Conclusion: Act V New York Times columnist David Brooks suggests the history of economics as a field of study has had four acts. Act I was the rise of basic economic theory, in which the first economists built models based on predictable human behavior. In Act II their successors complicated those models with more sophisticated ideas—such as the reality that people don’t always behave predictably. Act III, he believes, was the climax: the global economic crisis of 2008 and 2009 that economists completely failed to predict. Now, he suggests, we live in the aftermath: an Act IV in which those same economists are still trying to figure what happened, why it happened, and how to stop it from happening again. For the first time, many are looking at psychology, neuroscience (the study of the brain), and sociology (the study of society), to understand why human beings make the decisions they do. Why do so many people—and governments—spend more than they earn on things they don’t need? Why do people vote for policies that harm them, or complain about cheap foreign labor even as they buy its products? In short, why are people inconsistent, and why do they make so many mistakes? Brooks suggests the future of economics, if it answers those questions, may not look like economics today: “Economists will be able to describe how some people acted in some specific contexts. They will be able to draw out some suggestive lessons to keep in mind while thinking about other people and other contexts—just as historians, psychologists and novelists do. At the end of Act V, economics will be realistic, but it will be an art, not a science.” Not all economists are as pessimistic about the future of their field. But the growing complexity of the world is ever harder to analyze and predict. Faced with the same sort of economic crisis, the United States chose to spend more, the United Kingdom less. Neither strategy has been a clear success. Though the United States may be recovering sooner, it is, some would say, doing so at a greater cost. Economies are emerging from the Great Recession—or plunging deeper into it—only to discover that nothing is the same anymore. Some analysts believe China is on the verge of becoming the world’s leading economic superpower, eclipsing the United States and Europe; others argue that beneath its glittering new facade it is racing toward recession and collapse. Once a superpower in its own right, Russia is on the move, strengthening ties with allies in Central Asia and the Middle East, such as Iran and Syria—but will the return of Vladimir Putin as president spark a rebellion from within? Greece may yet fall; Italy may leave the Eurozone. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 137 The fragile economic recovery may be especially jeopardized by rising oil prices, even if they benefit certain countries, such as Russia. “If the world wants to make the region insecure, we will make the world insecure,” an Iranian government official has stated, warning that Iran could close the Strait of Hormuz—instantly cutting off 30% of the world’s oil supply. Israel may or may not take military action against Iran, which may or may not be developing nuclear weapons; the United States may or may not support it if it does. Rising oil prices, the Eurozone crisis, global climate change, growing food shortages, unpredictable geopolitical tension, stubborn unemployment—the world economy has a fragile back and is dodging a hundred straws. Analyze those straws using what you’ve learned in this guide. Put yourself in the shoes of today’s global leaders and ask, “How did this happen? Where do we want to go? And how do we get there?” In a few years, those leaders will be you134, and Act V yours. 134 That, or you will be one of their powerful economic advisors, as Jeffrey Sachs was to Boris Yeltsin. ECONOMICS RESOURCE | 138 About the Authors Daniel Berdichevsky likes to accumulate frequent flier miles in order to visit freezing cold countries in the middle of winter. As a senior, Daniel led the Taft Academic Decathlon team to its second national championship; a jaywalking ticket then turned him into a factor of production. Since then, he has founded DemiDec and the World Scholar’s Cup, managed a venture fund, worked as a busboy, bookseller, and ghostwriter (just once, for the Secretary-General), dropped out of three universities, and acted in a Taiwanese film about Santa Claus. Randy Xu likes to think he puts the con in economist. He has opened and closed credit card accounts just to accumulate introductory miles—and that was before he discovered hotel points. He also routinely deposits promotional 0% APR balance transfers into interest-bearing certificates of deposits. After graduating from Harvard, Randy designed energy trading software in New York before deciding to go into law after being arrested and detained for two days by the NYPD. He figured it would be cheaper in the long-run than hiring a lawyer. In 2000, Randy led the Simi Valley Academic Decathlon team to their first victory at the California state competition. Twenty years from now, Randy is sure he will be in prison, but is unsure if it will be for environmental activism, tax fraud, insider trading, or anti-trust violations. Tania Asnes lives in New York City, where she knows both Occupy Wall Street protestors and Wall Street bankers. She finds they understand each other more than the media lets on. Her preferred method of stimulating the United States economy is to purchase movie tickets.135 She also stimulates the economy of South America by purchasing too much yerba mate tea. 135 This may also double as her way of learning the nooks and crannies of the film industry, which she plans to infiltrate.