Commonwealth and the economics of development by Teodoro
Transcription
Commonwealth and the economics of development by Teodoro
I : . COMMONWEALTH AND THE ECONOMICS OF DEVELOPMENT TEODORO MOSCOSO and HUBERT BARTON Since World War II, international economic development strategy has focused on investment. Patterns of investment have varied depending on the resource mix of different developing countries and on differences in the roles of the government and private sectors in investment decision making. In Puerto Rico, government has actively promoted and subsidized private sector investment in agriculture, manufacturing and tourism and has itself invested directly in the essentials of economic infrastructure notably education, health, public utilities and trarisportation. This is the essence of what has been recently baptized as "supply side" economics but it has been de facto government strategy in Puerto Rico during most . of the last four decades. This is not to say that there has been an official, clearly articulated policy of investment priorities for the past forty years. Not all political leaders in San Juan and Washington have recognized the primacy of investment in the development process nor has there been anything like concensus on who should invest nor on how investment can best be maximized and guided into the most productive channels. Over the years, there have been numerous shifts in the details of development policies and in the roles of the government agencies involved. Some changes have been planned and deliberate, others have been inadvertent,' even accidental. Some have been related to the political status of Puerto Rico, others have not. The economic development history of Puerto Rico is rich in the diversity of the techniques employed but it has also had a consistent focus on investment in both human and material resources. l • -2In the 1930's much of the "investment" in Puerto Rico reflected remedial actions taken by the Federal government to deal with the ravages of the great depression. The principal agency involved was the Puerto Rico Reconstruction Administration (PRRA) . This well run Federal "work relief" agency reported that 79¢ out of each dollar of PRRA wages was spent for food and clothing imported from the States so that little PRRA money was left in the Island for ~·second or. third commercial turnover". It was recognized by PRRA that the "open" nature of the economy limited the "multiplier" effect of consumer expenditures in Puerto Rico in comparison with the United States or other economies in which most of the goods and services consumed are produced domestically . .Thus, deficit spending by government ori anti-poverty programs, which can be sound "demand side" economics in a large integrated economy, is much less effective in a small, island economy. It should be noted that about two-thirds of the Federal funds flowing into Puerto Rico today go directly to individuals. An even smaller proportion is invested than had been by PRRA half a century ago. Such Federal expenditures are of great social benefit since they flow to low income families and individuals. They have made the pattern of income distribution in Puerto Rico among the most egalitarian in the world. However, their effect on the economy is limited and transitory. In fact they probably contribute more to the U.S. economy than to the economic development of Puerto Rico. PRRA investments, however, left a legacy for Puerto Rican development in the 40's and into the 50's-- .. , -3- a cement plant that was transferred to the Industrial Development Company and plans for other enterprises that were undertaken by the Company during World War II. Even more important was the training of a cadre of young Puerto Rican planners and administrators who would provide dynamic leadership for the reorganized and revitalized Insular Government created during the 1941-46 administration of Governor Tugwell. 1940 Zimmerman The 1930 Brookings Reportl/ and the Report~/ had stressed the need to improve the quality of the Insular Government and the governments of the municipalities which were not only ineffectual but riddled with petty corruption. Governor Tugwell, with the support of Senator Munoz, built a modern, action-oriented executive branch and staffed it at the top with technically trained and highly dedicated individuals from PRRA and elsewhere. The financial muscle for the rapid development of the economic infrastructure of the Island during the 1940's and early 50's was provided by an unprecedented revenue windfall. About $160 million in "extra" Federal excise taxes on Puerto Rican rum sold in the States during the World War II whiskey shortage was returned by Federal law to the Insular treasury. By comparison, Insular Govern- ment receipts from all sources had amounted to only $28 million in 1939-40. ll Puerto Rico and its Problems, The Brookings Institution, Victors. Clark and Associates, Washington~ D.C., 1930. ~/ Staff Report Interdepartmental Committee On Puerto Rico, Washington, D.C., 1940. ... "' . . . -4Nearly all of this windfall was invested in nine government corporations instead of being , spent on the immediate consumption needs of an impoverished population. It was a hard decision for a young, populist government but the new corporations soon began to have a financial life of their own. By 1950 they were generating $38 million in annual sales, borrowing $41 million from private sources, retiring $17 million of debt and investing $32 million in expanded facilities. They received only $14 million from the public treasury and as time went on they became even more independent of government contributions. By 1950, total public debt had risen to $168 million from the very low figure reached at the close of World War II. Debt of the public corporations was $122 million, 73% of the total. The corresponding figures for 1983 are, total public debt, $8,440 million of " which the public corporations account for $6,276 million or 74%. Most 0£ this debt was then and is now externally held and it is clear that the public corporations have been the primary generators of public funds used for economic devel.o pment financing. Total public debt which was 23% of annual Gross Domestic Product in 1950 is 50% today. Debt financing has accelerated economic development and, as evidenced by the ratings of Puerto Rico bond issues, both investment policy and debt management have been generally productive as well as prudent. Puerto Rico's current problem is not an unmanageable public debt, as in many of the developing countries, but rather the recent decline in the proportion of its Gross Product that is spent for investment. It was ... -513% in 1950, 21% in 1960, 30% in 1970, 15% in 1980 and 10% in 1983. The increase in investment during the 50's and 60's and the drastic decline after 1972 was mainly in the private sector, which can be influenced but not controlled by government. Most of the nine original public corporations and some 30 others that have been established since are performing conventional public utility functions: electric power, water supply and sewage disposal, telephone, public housing, mass transit and construction and maintenace of ports, highways and public buildings. Some were established or purchased from private own'e rs to enable lower cost financing of construction and . a more rapid expansion of operations via the sale of municipal bonds ~han could have been financed either fro.m the general budget of the government or through private corporate borrowing. the University of Puerto Rico and the Others, like In~titute of Culture, were constituted as public corporations mainly for administrative convenience, combining a degree of general public control and financial support with internal operating autonomy and independence from the rigidities of central government personnel, budgetary and procedural regulations. All were expected to operate with the efficiency of private e~terprise but for public purposes. At first, nearly all of them did. Three of the original nine corporations, the Development Company, the Land Authority and the Agricultural Company, were established to own and operate factories, farms and supermarkets and sell their output at competitive market prices, functions traditionally regarded as . belonging in the private sector. The Government Development t -6- Bank also had a private sector lending function as well as its primary responsibility for acting as fiscal agent for the Insular and municipal governments and for the public corporations. The traditional boundries between the public and private sectors that prevailed prior to the depression and World War II were no longer sacrosanct. However, administration of some agencies of government, especially in the field of agriculture, became increasingly difficult for lack of clear definition of purpose and functions. As seen by Munoz, the basic responsibility of the Land Authority was land . reform, which had been a principal campaign pledge in his election campaign, while Tugwell was more concerned with agricultural development, production of food crops for lpcal consumption and fostering cooperative enterprises. The Land Authority was the first of the original nine public corporations to be established and it had the highest capital appropriations. The Agricultural Company was intended to be a development company. It was funded in 1946 at the end of Tugwell's administration as the last of the original nine public corpoiations. Its liquida- tion was recommended only four years later by the Planning Board in its first Economic Report because ''In the case of the Agricultural Company, the desire for financial success has tended to rest;ict expenditure on purely developmental activities, while the developmental character of certain of its activities has forstalled any chance of commercial success." The Planning Board recommended in its first three Economic Reports that the Land Authority be given a separately funded developmental subsidiary but the •' ' -7necessary legislation was vetoed or dropped. Puerto Rico has never had an effective agricultural· development organization. Government expenditures "on agriculture" have averaged about four times those on manufacturing development but, for the most part, they have been for rural social programs rather than for agricultural development. By 1950 the Land Authority had purchased nearly half the sugar land owned by private corporations in excess of the unenforced Federal "500 Acre Limitation Act". About 64,000 acres were put into 48 large "proportional benefit" farms which operated on a profit sharing system. About two-thirds of these farms were profitable in 1950 and their workers received a share of the profit in addition to the going wage of about $1.25 a day. In its early sugar operations the Authority was accomplishing a kind of land reform but it made little contribution to agricultural development and its original base in sugar production has now been almost completely eroded. There were 87,000 field workers employed in sugar cane production and 11,000 in the mills in 1950. There were also about 51,000 workers, mostly rural women engaged in home needlework. Today, only 4,000 workers ·have jobs in the sugar industry and home needlework has completely disappeared. A subsidiary of the Land Authority, the Sugar Corporation ~stablished in 1973 now owns and operates what little remains of the sugar industry into which it has poured well over half a billion dollars of public funds in a vain salvage effort. Except in 1974, the Corporation's cost of producing sugar has been about double the market value of the sugar produced. -8- A more lasting aspect of land reform was accomplished by the transfer of tracts of Authority land of limited agricultural value to the Social Programs Administration for the resettlement of landless farm laborers and their families. By mid-1950, 23,610 families had been resettled in 169 rural communities at a cost of $2.6 million and these numbers were to about double before the program ended. Since these landless laborers were the poorest of the poor, the social justice of this land reform measure is evident. Its low cost was made possible by a highly developed system of self-help housing that is still being copied, often under USAID auspices, in the more densely populated underdeveloped countries. Employment in rural Puerto Rico is now very small, the total in agriculture being about 37,000. Rural population, however, is still in excess of a mi.llion people, partly as a result of land reform and the many other social programs intended to improve the quality of life in rural areas. Most homes are owner occupied, nearly all have electricity and public water supply and fewer than one in five has more than one person per room. Most worke~s commute to work in their own cars but public vehicle routes I blanket rural areas and factory employment has been spread to every municipality in the Island. Rural areas have become pleasant and accessible low density bedroom communities for the more densely populated town and cities. Land reform was a political necessity in 1940. Like the frontier in early U.S. history, it held out the hope of escape from economic slavery and extreme poverty. By 1950, however, it was no longer a real issue. Land . .. .. -9ownership was merely an asset--it was no longer a means of control and oppression over those who had none. How- ever, although economic slavery had been largely abolished, poverty had not. Government priorities, therefore, shifted from land reform to job creation and income generation. A minimum family income of $2,000 a year soon became the accepted development objective. In its first Economic Report in 1950 the Planning Board recommended an impeccable priority system for a government economic development budget with direct investment in industrial and agricultural development heading the list of Priority Group I and rural resettlement and public housing well down in Priority Group III. The problem was that, even before 1950, land reform programs and a land reform stance had been built into all government agricultural programs and agencies. Both the programs and the agencies themselves became invested . with a moral rectitude that prevented penetration of developmental ideas and even of matured projects into the agricultural scene. To defend the status quo in agriculture became synonymous with defending Puerto Rico . Puerto Rican intellectuals and artists, many of them advocates of independence, returned the favor. They have tended to delineate Puerto Rico as rural long after this was the fact and to portray the (usually elderly) rural Puerto Rican as tha embodiment of "national" virtue. With some recent exceptions like the Israeli projects on the South Coast, outside investors in agriculture have seldom _ received effective support from the .. . -10agricultural bureaucracy and efforts by other government agencies to promote and develop agricultural projects and agro-industries have been declared ultra vires. Many critics of Puerto Rico's economic develop- ment policy complain that government abandoned agriculture. They are wrong, it was killed with kindness. The industrial development program resembled the agricultural program in several ways. Both programs were administered by a public corporation, both received initial public financing in 1942 with most of the rum windfall coming in 1946 and both invested initially in production facilities which they themselves would manage and operate. But there was one critical difference-- the Land Authority bought farms that were already in production while the Industrial Development Company financed and built new factories. The Land Authority changed the pattern of land ownership and the distribution of . agricultural income but it made little change in the total investment in agriculture, in technology or in total production and income. The Industrial Development Company, however, was "developmental". It inherited, expanded and operated the PRRA cement plant and it invested in, built and operated a structural clay products and sanitary ware plant, a glass bottle plant and a paperboard mill. By 1947 it also had a· shoe factory and several handicraft projects in operation plus plans and financing for what were to become the Textron cotton mill and the Caribe Hilton Hotel. These establishments were to be built and owned by the Company but to be privately managed and operated. .. ' -11- Getting these operations underway in wartime was uncommonly difficult. Priorities had to be obtained for equipment and materials. all that was available. Used equipment was sometimes Installation and maintenance problems were magnified by delays in deliveries, lack of experienced personnel and market uncertainties. Many mistakes were made, some were corrected, others could not be. Most problems were not attributable to the fact that the Development Company was itself a government entity. But some were. With Munoz as President of the Senate and Tugwell as governor, government was being professionalized but the general political orientation of its leaders was pro labor with populist and socialist leanings. ~trongly Labor relations in the new plants had no adequate philosophical or institutional underpinnings. Even among the· regular agencies of government there was as yet no well established civil service "merit system''. Strikes at the cement plant and the glass plant were protracted and costly. The under- lying conflict between the longer range development objectives of government and the shorter range objectives of organized labor had not been resolved and it persists today in our public utilities. The ordinary considerations of collective bargaining do not apply when labor. knows that there is nothing to prevent a utility company from continually financing wage increases by successive increases in rates. Even with problems like these, the Industrial Development Company (PRIDCO) would probably have continued its program of direct investment had we not realized that -12we would soon run out of investment funds. With most of the Company's original appropriations invested or committed with the war induced rum bonanza coming to an end and with only a small net income from Company operations, expansion would cease. were needed. Some 2,000 jobs had been created but 100,000 The idea of promoting or attracting private investment in manufacturing and tourism projects was not new but how to do so effectively and at a reasonable cost had to be worked out. Exemption from corporate income taxes was believed, a priori, to provide the strongest incentive and at a very low cost. However, Governor Tugwell vetoed the tax exemption bill we introduced in 1944. We were offering rental factory buildings which had ~roved to be mildly successful in Mississippi's BAWI program but this inducement standing by itself did strong enough in more distant no~ · · seem to be and unfamiliar Puerto Rico. We had ·a small office in New York, we had produced a modest promotional booklet and we had placed some experimental advertising. We also had a labor cost advantage as compared with the federated states. After a witless application of the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938 with its 25 cent an hour minimum had shut down most of the existing apparel industry, Puerto Rico obtained an amendment to the Act which enabled special industry committees to recommend minimum wages in Puerto Rico below the Federal statutory figure. As a result of this special provision of the Act, average hourly earnings of manufacturing production workers were considerably below the Federal statutory minimum through the 1950's, t. · " -13about equal to the Federal minimum in the 1960's but they rose far above it in the 1970's. During the SO's and 60's this special provision in the Fair Labor Standards Act for Puerto Rico (also for the Virgin Islands and American Samoa) served us well. Lower labor costs were usually the only cost advantage enjoyed by new manufacturing operations established in Puerto Rico as compared with their competitors in the States. Exemption from income tax has zero incentive value unless a company is making profits that would otherwise be taxable. The labor cost advantage made tax exemp- tion meaningful, once a workable tax exemption law was finally passed in 1947. Five years after PRIDCO was established we thus had the basic' legal and institutional environm~nt that would enable and even foster a program . for the promotion of private investment in manufacturing and tourism industries. We had an embryonic overseas promotion base in New York and a local organization that could provide rental buildings and some "special incentives" (subsidies), a growing understanding of the interests and requirements of corporate and individual investors plus the key factors: a labor cost advantage, e x emption from corporate profits taxes and duty free access to the U.S. common market, then and now the largest in the world. At the time, no other developing country had so favorable an institutional and political environment. This is one reason why many outsiders have denigrated the subsequent success of the "Fomento" program and the unprecedented rate of increase in employment and incomes that .. .' ' -14was - achieved in the SO's 60's and early 70's. Up to a point these critics are justified in regarding the Puerto Rican development program as ~ special case. They tend to forget, however, that "duty free access" is a two-way street and that nascent industry in Puerto Rico had no protection from established industry in the mainland with its many advantages of scale, location and markets. In all likelihood Puerto Rico would still be at a stage of development and a level of living below .that of Cuba or the Dominican Republic had it not enjoyed these special advantages in its relations with the United States. Cer- tainly our natural resource endowment is very scanty compared to that of our larger Caribbean neighbors. We had already learned, however, that the mere existence of incentives is not enough to attract .investment in manufacturing and tourism. The underlying l°egal and institutional incentives provided by territorial status had existe~ for many years, some of them since 1898--yet little investment had been attracted. It remained for a purposive and planned development effort to seize upon them, shape them, legislate an effective incentive program and then implement it. The incentive ingredients of the program were largely defined by 1947 but its implementation has been an evolving promotion process. At the outset, the kinds of investment needed by Puerto Rico were qliite unfamiliar to U.S. investors and virtually unknown to investors in Puerto Rico. U.S. over- seas investment had been largely confined to mining and agricultural operations to obtain raw materials needed by U.S. industry or to establish plants abroad to manufac- . , -15ture U.S. consumer products for sale within host countries having high tariff barriers. Neither manufacture abroad to obtain a lower cost ·product for sale at home nor building a hotel abroad for American tourists was a familiar practice. An entirely new set of factors was involved in making such investment decisions. Corporate investors, moreover, are notoriously conservative and our surveys showed that only a few of them knew enough about Puerto Rico and our development program to even consider it as a plant or hotel site. For most firms that were persuaded in the early years to establish an operation in Puerto Rico it was to be their first experience overseas. Since then such overseas investment in production facilities has become an established practice in Europe and Japan as well as in the United States. Investment promotion efforts, however, are even more necessary than before and much more costly. Dozens of very low wage countries throughout the world, dozens of countries with a variety of tourism attractions as well as almost every state of the United States and province of Canada are now in competition for investment dollars and the jobs they will create. Investment promotion is no longer the sale of a new idea. It has become competitive selling of the specific advantages of each country site. tive, it became more e x pensive. As it became more competiMore advertising space and time and more sophisticated techniques were required to stand out from the competition and capture the attention of potential investors. Mo r eover, other factors increase costs as a program of investment promotion begins to yield results. ,. . -16As the economy expands it requires increasing amounts of investment to maintain any given rate of economic growth, while a growing population with rising economic and social expectations creates pressures for an accelerating growth rate. Moreover, the development process itself tends to increase some production costs, notably wage rates, thus reducing a "natural" competitive advantage and increasing the need for promotion and its costs. Our investment promotion program began to produce results almost immediately. By the end of the 1953 fiscal year 213 newly promoted .plants were in operation employing over 18,000 people. Tourism also increased rapidly follow- ing the opening of the Hilton. Year round occupany averaged 75% in the tourism hotels and embarrassing room shortages occurred during the January-March peak. The rum promotion program with an annual budget of $1 million was yielding more than $10 million of extra revenue for the Commonwealth Treasury. Construction was well advanced on the Port Develop- ment project in Puerto Nuevo and the new Isla Verde airport. We had outgrown our basic infrastructure and would outgrow the new port and airport even before they were completed. These Fomento programs and projects were creating jobs and income, expanding the economy as a whole at a more than 7% annual rate and in spite of tax exemption, providing millions of dollars of additional Treasury revenue. Yet budget reductions wisely made in anticipation of the 1954 recession were unwisely concentrated in the Priority I Fomento programs which were cut from about 7.5% of the total budget in 1953 and earlier years to 4.8% for 1954, a trend which, with some interruptions, still continues. Today \.'! . -17the Fomento budget is less than 1% of the Commonwealth total. The effect .of these early budget reductions on operations was blunted by a 1950 reorganization of PRIDCO that had spun off its non revenue producing functions (promotion, research, technical services, general administration) to form a new regular government agency, the Economic Development Administration (EDA) to be funded - by the annual government budget. PRIDCO remained as a nearly self-financing subsidiary of EDA, financed by the earnings from its extensive real estate and more limited lending operations and, in the process, expanding its assets and borrowing capacity. 1983.) (Total assets were $483 million in Together, the two organizations became known as Fomento (Fomento Econ6mico and Fomento Industrial). Operating unity came from the top with the Administrator of ED.A acting as the board of directors of PRIDCO. PRIDCO's continued status as a public corporation enabled all of Fomento to act expeditiously and decisively in d~aling with its investor clientel and helped Fomento per~onnel to avoid some of the more frustrating restric- tions of a well meaning bureaucracy, especially when operating overseas. This attracted the action oriented achievers needed by a promotional organization and Fomento soon earned its reputation as an elite organization. Unfortunately, neither its reputation for performance nor the basic importance of its function gained Fomento the financial support it needed after investment promotion became more difficult and much more expensive. It had taken years to convince strong minded governors .. -18' and loyal legisl~tors to enact tax exemption. Now that it was working they would say "Why do you need more money-you have tax e x emption . " This sounds like the conventional wisdom of bureaucrats but the Fomentd program had other and more thoughtful critics. As early as the late 1950's, a number of responsible people, including the governor, began to have doubts about the matter of "balance" in our social and economic progress. Was the economic outpacing the social? Certainly industrial development was outpacing agriculture. Were local entrepreneurs being displaced by outsiders? Was Puerto Rico's cultural identity being jeopardized by urbanization and massive migration to the U.S. mainlan~? Should government efforts be concentrated on improving some of the conditions of Conunonwealth status? Underlying much of this questioning ahd criticism was undue faith in the Fomento program . have become automatic. It appeared to It was pushing up the economy every year at a rate that would double incomes every decade. There was still widespread poverty but it was disappearing rapidly. Jobs were waiting in the States for . those who could not find one at home. reached $3,000 . Average family income had Only some minor adjustment in the flow of income was needed to meet our $2,000 a year minimum income goal. Critics with $10,000 a · year incomes were already complaining about the "consumerism" of a $3 , 000 a year middle class. They could live well enough and even with "serenity" if only-- Walden like- -they would t ,r im their wants to what they could now afford. ' .. -19De facto changes in budget priorities made in response to opinions such as these were formalized in a 1968 report of a legislative commission for the study of "The l?urpose of Puerto Rico". The Commission was inspired by former Governor Munoz and its report was candid in advocating a change in the 1950 priorities: "The rapid and continuous development of the Puerto Rican economy in recent years has reached a point at which, with more than 3,300 million dollars of gross product a year and with an annual growth of 11 percent, priorities in legislative and governmental effort can be changed so as to attack more directly the problems that must be resolved in attaining the kind of civilization to which the people of Puerto Rico aspire." The "problems" ,to be attacked more directly were education, health, housing, rui~l development,!ocal entre- preneurship and, last on the list, poverty. Even in local entrepreneurship and the attack on poverty, Fomento was given no special role. It was tacitly assumed that its contribution and the eleven percent growth rate of the economy would automatically continue. Events were to prove otherwise. The year 1968 marked the end of the long period of rapid and sustained economic growth that had begun about 20 years earlier. It also marked the election of the first of the recent administrations th~t favored statehood for Puerto Rico. Statehood would automatically deprive us of the tax exemption and minimum wage advantages which, along with duty free access to the U.S. market, had enabled Fomento to function and generate the income that could . . . .: -20finance "The Purpose of Puerto Rico". Investors were, of course, fully aware of this situatioh so that even the very remote practical possibility of statehood made those with existing operations hesitant to expand and prompted many new investment prospects to look elsewhere. Our minimum wage advantage had already begun to weaken by 1968. Until then, flexible minimum wage rates established in accordance with the ability to pay of the different industries covered by the Act had held average hourly earnings of all production workers in Puerto Rico to a figure fairly close to the overall statutory minimum prevailing in the States. However, it allowed six large, labor intensive industries employing 70,429 production workers in 1968 to operate with average hourly earnings of $1.43 compared with the Feder_a l statutory minimum of $1.60. By 1976 average hourly earnings in these six lower wage industries had been pushed up to $2~36 and the number of jobs had been cut back to 53,275, a loss of more than 17,000 jobs that had taken years of effort to create. In the face of this job loss, the Chamber of Commerce of Puerto Rico petitioned the Congress in 1977 to postpone until 1979 the application to Puerto Rico of a further increase in the Federal statutory minimum. The statehood oriented government of Puerto Rico, however, disassociated itself from the position of the Chamber and urged that Puerto Rico be treated like a state to which the increases in the statutory minimum would automatically apply. This idealistic position of the Government has earned wage increases of about $1.00 an hour for the production workers remaining in these six industries but, .. ' . -21by March 1983, another 12,000 of them had lost their jobs. On that same date the annual Census of Manufacturing Industries showed total employment of manufacturing production workers about 2,000 below the figure that had been attained by October 1968. Loss of existing jobs is only part of the cost of excessively rapid wage increases. Another and larger loss is the new jobs that do not materialize because profit expectations in the industry have declined, investors have lost interest and projects are abandoned by their sponsors I on account of the increase in labor costs. In addition, there is an indirect job loss in the secondary industries like trade and services that depend on the primary income generated by manufacturing. An examination of the market position of the apparel industry suggests that the most serious damage inflicted by excessive wage · increases is curtailment of new investment. In 1968~ Puerto Rico shipped $370 million of clothing to the United States, accounting for 30% of the $1,226 million total of U.S. apparel imports. By 1974, U.S. apparel imports had nearly doubled, rising to $2,299 million. Meanwhile, however, apparel wages in Puerto Rico had been pushed up by 87 cents an hour, from 13¢ below the Federal statutory minimum in 1968 to 4¢ above it in 1976. New investment in the industry virtually ceased and shipments f~om Puerto Rico declined slightly to $363 million, amounting to only 16% of U.S. imports. We lost nearly half our share of the U.S. apparel market in less than a decade. In 1968, 38,168 production workers were employed in the apparel industry. Had the industry kept pace with .. . < ' . ' -22total U.S. apparel demand and retained its 30% market share, production worker employment would have almost doubled by 1974, say to about 70,000, and might easily have reached something like 100,000 by 1983 as U.S. imports of apparel continued to e x pand. Actual 1983 production worker employ- ment in the apparel industry, however, was only 28,062. Employment loss plus the deficiency in new jobs in the apparel industry has thus amounted to about 70,000 during the past 15 years. There were similar employment losses in other low wage industries that had also previously benefited from flexible administration of the Fair Labor Standards Act. The sacrifice in jobs may have reached 100,000 in manufacturing with an approximately equal loss in the dependent sectors of the economy. Even though we can never know the exact numbers, it seems likely that over zealous administration of minimum wage legislation is responsible for most of the heavy unemployment burden we carry today. We are paying a doubly heavy price for our failure to defend the system of flexible minimum wages since, without this flexible control over labor costs, corporate income tax exemption became meaningless for many manuf acturing operations, especially in the low wage industries. Tax exemption is not an incentive unless a firm earns a profit that would otherwise be taxable. For most manufac- turing operations, all important costs except labor costs and property taxes are higher in Puerto Rico than in the United States. It usually takes a_labor cost advantage to make a firm profitable in Puerto Rico but, once profitable, it can be doubly so because of exemption from corporate income taxes. I ' -23- Since the early SO's Fomento has been well aware of the limitations imposed by high costs on our efforts to attract investment in new enterprises. Its daily efforts have been focused on finding and promoting projects that fit into what cost advantages we have had and its longer range plans have been designed to open up new areas of competitive advantage into which our promotional efforts could be directed. The success of the Fomento program has been mainly founded on the imagination, technique and mass of its investment promotion effort. Here we pioneered and among our many disciples only those governments willing to donate a bigger budget have obtained comparable results. In the creation of new industrial opportunities we have been less succeisful and so has everyb?dy else. One of our earliest efforts dates from . the mid-SO's when we tried to create a center for industrial research and ' development in Puerto Rico that would lead to the establish- ment of high technology factory operations based on successful research. It took years of effort, we even bought the necessary . land, before it became clear that the only incentive that would enable development of a center that would be competitive with those already existing around major universities in the United States and Europe was personal tax exemption for the scientific personnel involved. It was the only si~nif icant attraction that would be unique to Puerto Rico and, therefore, effective in a competitive world. However, just as our first effective corporate tax exemption legislation was vetoed in 1944, personal tax exemption legislation for R&D experts was pocket vetoed thirty years later. < • • < -24We did have a few successes in opening new avenues for economic development. One of these was a food production complex that could satisfy much of the growing local market for high protein foods at a lower cost than direct imports. The key to lower costs was bulk imports of grains, promotion of large scale and efficient milling operations and of efficient processing plants for meat, milk, poultry and eggs. No one of these operations could have been successful without the others. It was economic development promotion as distinct from project promotion. A substantial number of other developmental projects were undertaken by Fomento, some successful like concrete reenforcing bars based on local scrap and rice milling based on more efficient bulk transportation of unmilled rice. Some like those based on paper · and paper- board manufacture from bagasse, the fibre byproduct of sugarcane, have been failures. By far the most ambitious of all these development projects was based on bulk import of low cost petroleum and a highly developed capital intensive complex of refineries and petrochemical industries intended to provide low cost materials for a variety of labor intensive fabricating industries. ·our e x perience in trying to build a strongly competitive pet~oleum based manufacturing sector is instructive because it illustrates both the advantages and the difficulties of developing an industry that derives its competitive capability from something other than lower wage rates. The economic and social advantages of higher wages are obvious. Wage rates of the production workers ' . • < -25- still employed in the oil refineries and petrochemical plants today are close to $10 an hour, double the manufacturing average and, of course, immune from the effects of increases in the statutory Federal minimum wage which is now only $3.35. The difficulties of developing such high wage industries in an island comparatively remote from almost all sources of industrial raw materials and from its principal markets may not be so evident. The principal motivation for constructing the two small oil refineries established in Puerto Rico in 1947 and 1955 was increasing local demand for fuel oil and gasoline. Although the refineries were granted tax exemp- tion and had considerable support from Fomento, they were mainly private entrepreneurial initiatives an existing market situation. re~ponding to These plants consumed low priced Venezuelan crude, sold fuel oil and gasoline at prices below those prevailing in the States and were initially quite profitable to their sponsors and owners. Fomento saw in this experience a related opportunity to introduce a low material p~iced economically transportable raw into the base of the economy on which to build a downstream complex of basic and intermediate petrochemical plants. More important for job creation would be the sub- sequent promotion and development of fabricating plants producing finished plastic products, synthetic fibers, rubber and a variety of paints ~nd finishes. Shortly after the start up of the first small petrochemical operation . of Union Carbide in 1959, however, this development plan was interrupted ..:by the imposition of mandatory quotas on imports of low-priced crude and unfinished oils. .. ~. ' -26After about five years of government-to-government negotiations, favorable treatment for Puerto Rican imports was obtained and foreign crude and naptha could again be imported at 30 to 45% less than U.S. prices. Thereafter, promotion and construction of new plants was very rapid. By 1973 a private investment of about $1.5 billion had been made in about 45 petrochemical plants and a few producing end products. Then, unexpectedly and unpre- dictably, OPEC price increases of about 400% intervened pushing overall 1974 operating costs in Puerto Rican petrochemical plants about Gulf Coast which 40% above those in the U.S. use domestic feedstocks. The past two decades (1964-74 and 1974-84) of the Puerto Rican petrochemical experience are .opposite faces of the same coin--input costs. Feedstock and energy inputs are a very high proportion of the total . : ~ost of petrochemical production, about 80% for a basic ethylene plant. (Even in the typical manufacturing operation materials costs exceed 5~% of total costs in contrast to about 15% for labor.) In petrochemicals during the 1964-74 period, savings in input costs more than covered payroll costs for many operations and high profits stimulated reinvestment and expansion. r ·n the subsequent decade the cost of inputs escalated, losses were prevalent, operations were shut down and some plants were dismantled and sold outside Puerto Rico. A small labor cost advantage · was obliterated by a very large disadvantage in materials cost. Other plans to develop materials based industries were frustrated by a change of administration. A joint ~. ' -27venture in steel, combining low cost steel from Venezuela with rolling mills and fabrication plants in Puerto Rico that would have unimpeded access to the U.S. market, was proposed by Fomento and a feasibilit y study jointly financed by the two governments demonstrated high probabilities of success. However, the Fomento expert in charge of the project was released by the new administration which was unable to obtain a qualified replacement to carry the project forward. Plans for a major shipyard met a similar· political fate as had long standing plans for copper mining, processing and fabricating. Development of a new industry takes time, far more than the promotion of an additional plant in an established industry that already has a number of successful plants. This puts a premium on continuity of policy and personnel in an economic development organization. Much .· of Fomento's success is attributable to its initial quarter century of policy and operating continuity. But government in Puerto Rico has failed to develop a strong public service tradition comparable to that in the United States and most countries of Europe. It is rarely found in developing countries but the records of Ireland, Israel and Barbados provide impressive evidence that it can be done and that it is worth doing. Continuity is important not only for complex industry developmeFlt plans but also in the "rules of the ' game" for what has become a fairly standardized and conventional program of investment promotion. Investors need constant reassurance that they are welcome, that their investment is needed and that they will continue to receive red carpet treatment. '. .. . . ' -28- Continuity does not mean that rules should be unchanged but it does mean that whatever changes are made should be in a positive direction. In 1·976, we finally negotiated with the U.S. Treasury and the Congress an advance in the attractiveness of our tax exemption program that we had sought since the 1950's. Enactment of Section 936 of the Internal Revenue Code permitted tax free repatriation of the profits of a subsidiary of a U.S. firm operating in Puerto Rico without liquidating the subsidiary, as had previously been required. A well meaning Congress, however, insisted that Puerto Rico itself impose a "tollgate'' tax on the profits being transferred as compensation for the loss of reinvestment in Puerto Rico that might otherwise take place . .This tollgate tax, though quite low, immediately became controversial. It was said to be an ex · post facto tax on the accumulated earnings of firms that had been promised 100% tax exemption. In. fact, it was not a tax on earnings but on their repatriation under Section 936. A more realistic objection was that if a firm opted to repatriate before setting up a reserve for the required tollgate tax, its securities would presumably drop in price because of the decline in current net income occasioned by current payment of the tax. The Commonwealth Treasury had, anq still has, a strong interest in .the tax because the firms interested in repatriation had very high earnings and even a low tax on repatriation promised a substantial tollgate revenue. As a matter of record, established firms have been able to accommodate their accounting to the tollgate tax and it ;. . -29- has yielded about a billion dollars in Cornmonweath Government revenue over the intervening years. From the standpoint of industrial promotion, however, the merits of this controversy are unimportant. What is important from a promotional point of view is that a 30 year record of continued liberalization of tax exemption seemed to have ended. Puerto Rico was made to appear less interested than it had been in attracting new investment, even though Section 936 itself actually provided a strong additional investment incentive. Existing investors would be pleased with the opportunity to repatriate profits but we could no longer offer "100% tax exemption", our strongest appeal to new investors and most direct route to additional investment and increased employment and income. The damage done to the program in 1977 by denouncing the flexible system of minimum wages and in 1~78 by enacting a watered down industrial incentives act was more fundamental and may be impossible to correct. As we have noted, denuncia- tion- of the flexible system of minimum wage administration resulted in a heavy loss of existing jobs in the lower wage industries. Less attractive tax incentives have hampered promotion of new jobs that would have replaced some of those that were lost. As a result of these program changes plus the loss of our petroleum price advantage and worldwide "stagflation", total factory employment in the last three fiscal years ('82 - '84) has averaged 145,400, somewhat ' below the corresponding period a decade earlier ('72 when it had already reached 146,900. Although total factory employment has declined somewhat, factory payroll and manufacturing Net Income '74) . " -30have continued to increase because of a change in the industrial structure or mix of manufacturing industries. Employment declines have been concentrated in low wage industries while higher wage, high profit industries, like pharmaceuticals and computers, have continued to expand. This gradual shift to higher wage industries was the result of the special appeal of tax exemption to high profit-high wage industries and of an early Fomento effort to promote industries that would have a larger investment and stronger roots in Puerto Rico and would pay high enough wages to be immune from minimum wage increases. A "Special Incentives'' program administered by PRIDCO offered subsidies for investment in "core" industries, high wage industries and others having special value for the program. During the 1950's and 60's, additional promotion efforts, including use of these PRIDCO subsidies, were focused on sue~ selected "target" industries. As they began to respond they provided visible "success stories" that could be literally shown to other prospective i~vestors who were often unaware of . the diversity of the manufacturing operations that had already been established in Puerto Rico. Since many of these "target" industries had high skill requirements in their manufacturing processes as well as for R&D, Fomento supported an early expansion in the Mayaguez College of Engineering which since 1960 has produced / three times more graduate engineers than have found employment in Puerto Rico. This ample supply of engineers has been an important factor in the current expansion of the computer industry for which the supply of electrical and electronic engineers is a critical locational 'factor. ' -. .·-. ''tt ...... -31It is sheer profitability, however, that has brought most of the high wage industries to Puerto Rico. Industries with a high R&D content ~ ~ave been producing "miracle" drugs, "quantum leaps forward" in information processing and communication equipment and many other revolutionary changes in processes a nd products. Much of this has been patentable and successful firms have been able to sell at prices yielding extraordinarily high profi ts--and correspondingly high income tax obligations. Ex emption from income tax could almost double an already high after tax profit--and it was available only in Puerto Rico. Moreover, as profits on industrial investments go, those realized on investments in Puerto Rico are quick to materialize. As soon as a plant could be put . into produc- tion it would almost double the profit that could be reported to stockholders. This has been of increasing .importance for U.S. corporate money managers and has strongly stimulated re~~nt promotion of high investment, high profit industries which are now almost alone in responding favorably to the current Fomento program. High profit industries like :pharmaceuticals, computers and scientific instruments, <an afford to pay high wages, construct their own manufacturing facilities and, hopefully, do some of their essential technical research in Puerto Rico. They also draw heavily on local business and professional services as well as generating income and consumer demand for other industries serving the local market. We are now benefiting from our early efforts to attract such industries. The successful record of plants established by General Electric, Westinghouse, Sylvania, Parke Davis, .. ... • l ,. .. .. ''&i ... . ' -32- Digital Equipment and many other firms promoted in the 1950's and 60's has led to the establishment of many more since then. But without question, our current overall economic development efforts fall far short of our needs. The level of income in Puerto Rico .·is less than a third the U.S. average and below the level of many small independent countries including Trinidad, Singapore, Israel and Ireland that learned much from our earlier development experience. We need not have lost so many jobs in the low wage industries. We have not yet negotiated with the U.S. Treasury or the Congress a durable role for Section 936 in the Federal component of tax exemption. Fomento has not had adequate budget support since the early 1950's. The shrinkage in its promotional organization and in available subsidy funds has accelerated in the last 10 years precisely when world economic conditions were worsening and competition for manufacturing and tourism investment funds was becoming more acute. The competition of the Far East and other low-wage developing countries for private investment in industry, tourism and agriculture has now been joined by the United Stat~s itself, which not only allows accelerated depreciation on domestic investment but also for U.S. investments in competing countries in the Caribbean Basin. In their efforts to force Puerto Rico to assume a "state like" posture, statehood advocates have cut our own tax incentives to q point where existing tax exemption has comparatively little net attraction for many U . S. industrial investors. U.S. investment incentives have become com- petitive with ours. Accelerated depreciation is said to have given the typical U.S. industrial f.irms an effective ... -33tax rate in the neighborhood of 14% compared with the long standing 48% rate. Our current tax "exemption" with however small a tollgate tax does not provide much tax advantage except in the few industries having very high rates of return legally attributable to their,manufacturing operations. The United States is not going to develop the economy · of Puerto Rico. Transfer payments to poor families and other Federal measures to relieve poverty will continue to apply to Puerto · Ricans because we are U.S. citizens. We can con- _ tinue to benefit from minorities legislation, especially in sales to the military. An "Enterprise Zone Act" would help some regions in the states but would probably add little or nothing to existing investment incentives in Puerto Rico. On the contrary, unless carefully drafted it ~ould increase the strong stateside competition for private investment dollars we are already facing. We do need help from Washington--kinds of help that could not be extended to any particular state but· have been and can be provided to us as a Commonwealth. We need legislated "permanence" for se:ction 936 and "most favored" tax treatment for U.S. corporate investments in Puerto Rico. Section 936 recognizes the fiscal independence of Puerto Rico. But merely as a matter of equity, it seems to us that if our government is willing to exempt the 936 corporations from tax, it is. not too much to ask the Treasury of the United States to fpllow suit. Similarly, it seems to us only fair and just for the United States to extend at least as favorable corporate tax treatment to firms investing in Puerto Rico that it does to those investing elsewhere in the Caribbean Basin. -34The rest is up to us--clarif ication and simplification of our own rules of the game, a fresh start in agriculture, unified administration of key economic development programs and an increase by multiples in the promotional efforts of a revitalized and reunified Fomento to stimulate investment from ·all available sources in every creative aspect of our economy and society.