A National Scandal: Wildly Inflated ... How to Slay Them? Introduction
Transcription
A National Scandal: Wildly Inflated ... How to Slay Them? Introduction
A National Scandal: Wildly Inflated Residential Property Values, and How to Slay Them? Introduction th In 2010, both The Economist (2010) and the 7 Annual International Housing Affordability Survey (Demographia, 2011) claimed Australian housing markets are some of the least affordable in the world, with the former suggesting house prices were overvalued by 63.2 percent – the most of any country – and the latter stating that five of the world’s six least affordable housing markets were located in Australia. As such, there is much contemporary debate in Australia about whether the country’s 5 major housing markets (Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane, Adelaide and Perth) are in the midst of an asset price bubble that is destined – like all such bubbles – to burst and damage the lives of many residents, or just reflect solid market fundamentals relating primarily to the balance of supply and demand for different classes of residential property. There is also debate as to whether a housing bubble, should it exist widely, can be corrected slowly and with little long-term disruption, or whether deflation might be rapid and economically destabilising for Australia’s financial system, as occurred in the United States at the start of the current global financial crisis. More importantly, debate is also hampered by weak theoretical conceptualisation of the processes shaping housing prices, market bubbles, and the affordability of residential real estate. Only if we examine closely these processes, will we be in a position to clarify whether bubble conditions currently exist and, should that be the case, whether they are likely to deflate slowly with a minimum of disruption. Since problem definition is conceivably the most crucial step in any empirical analysis, it is surprising that both academic analysis and media commentary have failed to tackle the concept of housing bubbles and define the exceedingly complex processes shaping housing prices. So, rather than attempting to identify the extent of any current housing bubble, we take a step back and analyse the processes shaping residential prices. Also, we cannot do this adequately without reflecting on the nature of economic uncertainty. Following recent work by Sorensen (2011) and its on-going refinement, one might legitimately conclude that the form and extent of a housing bubble is extremely difficult to define. Instead, we might merely be able to conclude that Australia’s housing prices tend to be excessive in several market segments, an outcome caused not by irrational exuberance on the part of the purchasers of real estate, but by mal-functioning internal market processes. We start, then, by analysing the dynamic processes shaping housing prices in our cities, emphasising in particular their highly complex and uncertain nature. This, in turn, leads us to identify what appear to be gross inefficiencies in Australia’s housing markets. Thirdly we consider the notion of economic bubbles in general and how the concept might apply to housing prices. Two important themes here are whether housing bubbles typically result from complexity, inefficiency, or aberrant behaviour on the part of would-be or existing homeowners or their investor counterparts. Finally, such analysis could suggest a raft of policy reforms to better constrain the boom and bust cycles in housing prices that typically create rafts and winners and losers from home ownership. We will leave it to others to decide quantitatively whether bubble conditions really exist or are an illusion, or indeed are ultimately unmeasurable. The Dynamics of Housing Markets House supply in one year comprises the stock of existing homes, which is usually over 98% of the total, and the flow of new accommodation on to the market. In a country like Australia, whose population grew > 2% in 2010, the relative proportion of flow (F) to stock (S) is crucial in shaping overall market prices. Where F > household growth (HG), market prices for homes will tend to ease, ceteris paribus, and vice versa if F < HG. So, flow is an important balancing item in housing markets. The Production of New Housing Goods (Flow) The production of new housing goods has two distinctive inputs: site and structure. In Australia, which is significantly different to many countries, the production of housing lots and the construction of homes are often in the hands of separate businesses. These, in turn, respond to the slightly different operating systems show in Figures 1 and 2. Table 1 enlarges on the sub-factors factors contributing to each of the major headings in the two diagrams and a quick tally of the entries shows over 60 variables in play, all potentially affecting the supply-demand for, balance for housing, and therefore its price. Similar considerations influence the prices of existing homes and/or the redevelopment of existing urban fabric. Both Figures 1 and 2 contain multiple feed-back loops and to some extent land and housing components are mutually substitutable. Figure 1: Factors Influencing the Price of Subdivided Land Supply of Raw Land Household Profile Third Party (regulator etc.) Developer Actions Economic Settings Household Income and demand - supply Funding System Demand Supply Quality of Subdivision Land Price Economic Settings Source: the authors Figure 2: Factors Influencing the Price of House Construction Economic Settings Behavioural Issues Third Party (regulator etc.) Actions Developer Actions Household Income and Expenditure Decision to Invest in Housing Goods Demand f or Housing Goods demand - supply interaction Quality of Construction Economic Settings Source: the authors Price of Housing Goods Supply of Housing Goods For example, would-be owners can opt for less land and larger structures – as with McMansions – or the reverse for those seeking environmental quality. Where the cost of subdivided land rises faster than construction costs, as happened over much of the last decade, aspiring owners will tend to opt for some combination of smaller lots and smaller dwellings according to taste. In the short run, flow is inelastic while demand often moves sharply up or down depending on the rate of immigration or rises and falls in consumer sentiment. New supply usually lags demand because of inherent delays in development approval and construction. The normal market response to rising demand is for house prices across the entire market (S + F) to increase until sufficient new supply enters the market, at which point real prices typically decline to previous levels (Mayer and Somerville, 2000). Additional Market Considerations Property markets are entangled in a raft of other dynamic, and often inter-connected, processes. We identify nine of these below: 1 At the time of purchase, the quantity and quality of housing goods sought by households tends to be a residual within their operating budgets after (a) the purchase of goods and services and (b) savings, are subtracted from income (see Figure 3). Once a household has committed to purchase, mortgage repayments become a fixed element in the equation and living expenses or savings adjust downwards to any reduction income. The initial residual is highly susceptible to upward spikes in household outlays, occasioned by unexpected rises in, say, transport, energy, and other infrastructure costs. The downward impact on house prices is fast, especially so in fringe locations where transport comprises a larger share of the budget than elsewhere in out cities. Likewise, the current need for households to increase savings rates and pay down debt looks like capping bid prices for homes for several years, as occurred throughout much of the 1990s in response to Australia’s 1990-01 recession. The Reserve Bank’s tightening of interest rates throughout much of 2010, increased government fees and charges, higher taxes, or general inflation in household goods will also tend to depress household residuals available for house purchase. Note that many of these processes will be spatially variable. 2 Demand for housing, and therefore prices, is also influenced significantly by non owner-occupiers, and especially (a) investors in rental housing; and (b) second-home owners. Demand in both these sectors is highly unstable, but they follow different imperatives. Investment in rental accommodation is particularly susceptible to rental income, which is in turn affected by demand-supply conditions in the sector; prices of real estate in general; borrowing costs; and the taxation regime including the treatment of negative gearing. Sometimes these circumstances conspire to work with the broader housing market co-cyclically and therefore accentuate booms and busts. On other occasions, especially where would-be owners cannot enter the housing market, rental demand and therefore rental income surges, encouraging investors in the sector. Second- (or trophy-) home demand is largely co-cyclical, surging in feel-good times, but rapidly dumped when economic conditions get tough as the large number of coastal properties on the market attests. This tends to compound housing cycles. Demand for both investment and trophy homes is also affected by market conditions for such alternative investments as commodities, shares and bonds, fine art, boats and aircraft, or collectables, not to mention their respective tax treatments. 3 The cycle of house price rises and falls is strongly skewed, as shown in Figure 4. Notice, in particular, that share markets fall heavily when they hit a bump, whereas house prices can rise quite quickly, but often then tend to fall slowly over a long period. This contrasting symmetry is easily explained. First, shares are highly liquid and can easily be bought and sold at a moment’s notice. Housing is often horribly illiquid, which means that buyers are sometimes trapped for the long term, and homeowners are often unwilling to sell at a loss into a declining market, especially if they are not under immediate financial pressure to do so. Secondly, the cost of buying and selling real estate is massively higher than trading in shares – typically between 3 and 6 times higher according to methods used. However, most home owners fail realise that slowly sinking house prices – by say 2% a year – over a five year period when inflation is running at perhaps 3%, will trash real house prices by nearly 25% while the owner is not looking. Thirdly, the fast run-up of house prices in the early stages of an upswing is often, as we suggested above, caused by delayed supply. 4 Governments often subsidise selected types of household to shoehorn them into home ownership at times of steely rising prices. First home owner assistance is a case in point, and has several malign effects on house prices. Such schemes accelerate rising house prices by inducing further demand Figure 3: Housing Outlays to Household Budget Housing Outlays to Total Budget - Household Budget - Price of Other Goods / Services Savings = Housing Outlays (residual) Trade-offs Between Housing and Other Expenses Source: the authors Figure 4: Cyclical Price Fluctuations in Housing and Stocks or Shares Real (inflation adjusted) Price ($) Stock & Share Prices Real Estate Prices 0 Time (years) 5 10 Source: The Authors against often sluggish housing supply. Indeed the price increases triggered by the subsidy will rise roughly to the level of the subsidy provided. This leads to the bizarre situation where early entrants to the scheme get a free meal ticket, while late entrants take a financial hair-cut as house prices for the target group take a dive when the scheme expires. Such absurd outcomes only make sense to politicians seeking votes. 5 Governments have had another interestingly perverse impact on house prices generally over recent decades. The adoption of a user pays regime for the infrastructure required by new fringe dwellers has meant that land prices have accelerated steeply ahead of house construction costs. Instead of funding much of this infrastructure through 3-part tariffs, where the whole community pays for urban expansion (i.e. community rating), those costs are now borne largely by new and often young homeowners. Existing residents, meanwhile, receive a financial bonus by paying cheaper 2-part tariffs. The much more expensive land coming on to the market flowed rapidly through to existing owners. This second financial bonus occurred because their homes suddenly became a lot more attractive to buyers compared with new land release areas. Thus, the wealthy get richer and the younger new homebuyers are slugged with additional heavy outlays. 6 Another important dynamic of property markets is the heterogeneity of both stock and flow properties. Table 2 lists 9 dimensions. This table suggests that we are not looking at one housing market, but a multitude, and that the cyclical rise and fall in house prices in each market segment will probably be asynchronous. Some segments will doubtless have either excess or deficient housing stock. The former’s prices may be considerably softer than the latter’s, but the extent of price differentials will depend on buyers’ inclination to move between segments – a process of substitution and trade-off. The extent to which market segmentation constitutes a problem for housing markets also depends partly on two issues: (a) how far conservative communities and/or developers can conspire to enforce their Weltanschauung and restrict additional supplies to their preferred housing type, and (b) the diversity and pace of emergence of social change. The latter includes delayed retirement; longer life expectancy; rising immigration; later marriage; and possible continued decline in average household size. These two dimensions could create major discordance between housing supply and demand, with associated residential price implications. 7 This raises another important issue affecting house prices. Housing spaces often conceal considerable inbuilt substitution possibilities, so that expected housing needs calculated by planners or developers may simply not emerge. Again, the options are myriad. Young people unable to buy suitable accommodation at a price they can afford may simply remain at home longer than they previously expected or wanted. Parents can move in with their children and create multi-generational households. Various kinds of group household can emerge unheralded. Oldies can downsize their accommodation, releasing space for larger households while they generate new lifestyles and the means to enjoy them. Some single properties can also be split into to two or more smaller units. Indeed, conventional economics can be almost suspended in some conditions. Long ago, Hirsch (1977) raised the notion of positional goods, and it is clear that in some of Australia’s higher priced residential markets, demand curves for housing are inverted: the higher the price, the more the demand. But equally obviously, economic issues revolving supply and demand interactions and the resulting price effects are critical to most players in the housing market. 8 Over the years, household capacity to pay for homes has been altered significantly by the loan periods offered to aspiring homeowners. For example, the steady move from 20 year to 30 mortgages has enabled households to borrow larger sums of money than previously, potentially pushing up house prices. The ever-increasing numbers of dual income families has had a similar effect, as has the ability of increasingly wealthy parents to bankroll partially their children’s dream of home ownership. It is not therefore surprising that Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) time-series data on monthly household expenditures shows little change in the proportion of gross incomes spent on housing costs for all households in the capital cities from 1995-2008 (Figure 5). Sydney and Adelaide show marginal growth in this index; Melbourne, Brisbane, Hobart, and Canberra all experienced no net change; and two cities, Perth and Darwin, showed a slight net decrease. This evidence suggests housing prices have not outgrown household incomes, which some believe to be a major indicator of inflated housing markets. Table 4 throws completely different light on the subject. Australia’s households are now immensely in debt, and the culprit is housing debt. The explanation for this difference, we suggest, is the extension in the terms of mortgages. Housing outlays as a proportion of incomes have remained fairly flat; but households have raised mortgage duration by 50% and total repayments even more. 9 Everything discussed so far suggests that different kinds of household may well have very different housing experiences, which in turn affects supply-demand interactions and outlays on accommodation. Some like the poor and unemployed, the young, and single-income families or those in large households are largely excluded from home ownership. Those on dual professional incomes, the Yuppie households, on the other hand have no problems paying off a mortgage, especially over longer time periods. In between is a constellation of household circumstances sometimes affected by such considerations as the ability of parents to subsidise their offspring with grants or a portion of the monthly repayments. Those forced into the private rental sector, the number itself affected by the supply of social housing, will in turn affect landlord’s profitability and their demand for housing spaces. In conclusion, the forces shaping housing markets and house prices are numerically large, heavily interconnected, dynamic individually and collectively, variable between both types of housing and types of household, operating at a confused private-public interface. Let’s just say at this stage that some communities have extensive power to manipulate market processes, via typical planning systems, to their own ends and at the expense of other segments in the housing market. NIMBY, LULU, or BANANA outcomes are deeply etched into regulatory systems. And even if they did not exist, politicians have rigged the game in other ways. People, for instance, do not like paying infrastructure fees and charges and, since existing homeowners of purchasers are in a large majority, why not cut their charges and load them on to the minority of home aspirants who exercise little voting power? Moving from three-part tariffs to two-part tariffs can achieve this. Table 2: Heterogeneity of Housing Stock Feature Indicative Range 1 Style Single dwelling units; Row housing; Apartments; Retirement Villages; Integrated developments; Gated communities 2 Density High, medium, or low 3 Amenity Specialist rooms (e.g. home theatre, billiard, children’s play area, garage space, numbers of bedrooms and their facilities like en suites, facilities for the handicapped) 4 Size Large through to small 5 Accessibility To specific facilities like the CBD, educational and medical facilities, shopping centres, sporting venues, clubs, restaurants OR To specific transport types (public or private; land or air) 6 Quality of Design Heritage, Art Deco, Federation, Modernist, Avant Garde 7 Quality of Construction High through to low 8 Social Amenity Cosmopolitan, Gender preference, Age groups, Social class, Ethnic groups 9 Environmental Quality Water views, parkland, air quality, minimal noise, pace of life Source: The Authors Percent Figure 5: Housing Costs as a Propor@on of Income 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 Sydney Melbourne Brisbane Adelaide Perth Hobart Darwin 1995 1996 1997 1998 2000 2001 2003 2004 2006 2008 Year Source: Australia Bureau of Sta@s@cs Canberra Land and Housing Market Inefficiencies At the heart of any economic analysis is the notion of efficiency. Efficient markets equilibrate supply and demand fast and are sufficiently competitive to the extent that the prices of goods and services should approximate their cost of production plus a normal profit margin. Costs include not only the inputs of capital and raw materials, but also labour and training, rents, research and development, innovation and opportunity costs. Normal profit levels expected by producers vary between industry sectors according to their riskiness, and the supply of new housing is sufficiently competitive among a large array of producers, large and small, for normal profits to prevail most of the time. That said, housing supply is more risky than many other industry sectors because demand fluctuates markedly and long lead times frequently mean that supply enters the market during down-turns in the business – consumer demand cycle. In other ways, housing markets operate like those for most other goods. In the long run, the level of housing production should approximate the level demand for new housing. This generally equates to the number of new households entering a given market. Housing is also a “normal” good, whereby the amount of housing “consumed” is generally a function of income - households typically increases the size and/or quality of their dwelling as incomes increase. However, in many ways housing markets are relatively unique when compared other to other goods, and the previous discussion reveals numerous inefficiencies in housing markets summarised in Table 5. We have classified these in three ways. The first, supply constipation, provides a considerable list of reasons why additional supplies of housing suitable to consumer – both homeowners and tenants – needs are often not provided in a timely way. Note that the difficulty lies largely in infrastructure supply and regulatory imperfection rather than developer deficiency, suggesting a considerable scope for public sector reform. The second, artificially inflated demand, simple notes that Australians probably sink far too much capital in residential real estate rather than alternative investment outlets because of a range of subsidies to home ownership and mantras surrounding home ownership. Their reduction or removal could go some way to reducing demand – supply imbalances. Finally, the extremely high cost of residential property transactions, when compared with share-market trades, reduces the speed with which market signals operate. The total cost of share transactions is usually < 1% of the purchase amount, while in housing the usual amount is 5 times that. We argue supply uncertainty and inefficiencies are perhaps most important with respect to high housing prices in Australia, and discuss in more detail below. Housing Booms and Housing Bubbles We now turn to the question of whether Australia’s house price movements over the last decade were in bubble territory or simply reflect usual supply – demand interactions between households and developers in a highly regulated production system. We should also remember the stock / flow problem mentioned earlier. Economists generally acknowledge that prices exceeding this cost-plus normal profit formulation are excessive and indicate a suboptimal market. Monopolistic and oligopolistic markets typically enable producers to charge higher consumer prices and earn super-normal returns. Housing markets are inevitably cyclical (Mankiw, 1989; Case 1992; and Ortalo-Magné and Rady, 1999) partly because, in the short run, supply is inelastic or difficult to ramp up, as we have seen. House prices will typically increase as extra demand is revealed until sufficient new supply can come onto the market, and then prices and new construction should fall back to previous levels (Mayer and Somerville, 2000). The problem for housing is that a rise in, say population growth from 1% per annum to 2% can effectively double the demand for new housing. Supply blockages will automatically tend to raise price quite sharply under such conditions. From a policy and empirical perspective, what is important in recognizing housing bubbles is whether rising prices are a result of economic fundamentals such as those just described, or because of other less rational factors. The term “housing bubble” is often used in popular media without a clear understanding of what distinguishes booming prices from bubble prices. This lack of understanding also exists in academic circles, and became more apparent with the crash of the US housing market and subsequent flurry of scholarly papers seeking to explain the “bubble.” As such, we will attempt to draw a definitions based on more objective scholarly works developed before the most recent housing market collapse in the US. Housing market booms and busts are quite natural for the reasons mentioned above. The size, length, and severity of house price increases and declines have varied over the past 100 years, and not all (or even many) crashes in the developed world can be attributed to bubbles. Many crashes occurred because of more fundamental drivers, such as excessive homeowner subsidies, distorted mortgage markets, overly restrictive land use regulation, developer speculation, and unsound monetary policy, and in general have followed almost every housing boom on record. Conceptually speaking, there is clear line between boom and bubble. The commonly accepted definition of a market bubble is price appreciation of an asset is high only because investors speculate future appreciation will be high, and disregard fundamental economic drivers (Stiglitz, 1990; Case and Shiller, 2003; and Himmelberg, Mayer, and Sinai, 2005). Specifically, Himmelberg, Mayer, and Sinai (2005) apply this definition to housing markets, who “think of a housing bubble as being driven by home buyers who are willing to pay inflated prices for houses today because they expect unrealistically high housing appreciation in the future.” As mentioned above, appreciating housing prices are not necessarily an indicator of an emerging bubble. Himmelber, Mayer, and Sinai (2005) suggest four reasons why this is so: (1) the price of a house is not indicative of the cost of owning a house, (2) rising housing prices say nothing about whether housing is overvalued, (3) differences in expected price appreciation and tax rates can lead to significant regional variation in house prices relative to rents, and (4) interest rates and expected changes in regional fundamentals greatly affect the sensitivity of house prices. Points (3) and (4) are of special importance because expectations of price increases alone are not causes of bubbles – only if expectations are rooted in current and past price appreciations. For example, if expected price appreciations reflecting anticipation of decreasing household size, increasing populations, increasing incomes, or decreasing interest rates, then expected price appreciations are rooted in fundamental economic determinants. Even if these expectations are exaggerated or miscalculated, a bubble will not likely emerge because “irrational exuberance” among buyers is lacking (Shiller, 2008). Case and Shiller (2003) poignantly describe that during housing bubbles “homebuyers think that a home that they would normally consider too expensive for them is now an acceptable purchase because they will be compensated by significant further price increases,” and that “first-time homebuyers may…worry…that if they do not buy now, they will not be able to afford a home later.” Shiller (2008) makes an intriguing argument that bubbles are inherently a psychological phenomenon, where societal beliefs of ever-increasing house prices grip public sentiment, and that these sentiments reflect serious “irrationality” in the market. On Uncertainty To us, housing markets look like one of the most uncertain economic systems imaginable. Myriads of players on the demand side, with diverse and often rapidly changing housing needs and abilities to pay for them, are competing for residential accommodation. Such conditions also exist on the supply side, except that the interactions of actors are far more confused and often contradictory. The supply side is a whole of society venture, with a conflicting mixture of parties representing private, government, and community interests, each of whom has different motives, agendas, time frames, access to power, and conceptions of the ideal living environment in various states of development. To make matters worse for all these supply and demand participants, governments and the wider community have virtually no power to control the changing technologies that ultimately shape urban life. Sorensen (2011) identifies 11 separate dimensions of uncertainty, all recognisable in our cities and all interconnected so that it difficult to explain events or observations in complex systems like those considered in this paper. The ultimate implication of this logic is that it may be difficult to say whether property markets have experienced bubble conditions or normal market uncertainty. So, given the above, the question remains: are Australian house prices in bubble territory, or are they within the range of normal expectations? The focus of this paper is not on quantitatively identifying housing bubble in Australia. Rather, our aim to develop a concise qualitative narrative on the potential emergence and causes of bubbles in Australian markets. We begin by suggesting that different types of bubbles may exist in different markets. While the scholarly literature above defines bubbles as scenarios where buyers are irrationally paying higher prices for homes because of unreasonable expectations of future price increases, it is plausible that irrationality may emerge for reasons other than misplaced exuberance. Rather, in hindsight what appear to be irrational decisions of homebuyers may simply be completely be rational decisions based on increasing uncertainty in housing markets. As such, we distinguish the housing bubbles in Australia into two types: irrational bubbles, marked by excessive and misplaced exuberance about house price appreciation, and uncertainty bubbles, marked by more rational decisions reflecting uncertainty in both the development process and future economic and political decisions. The distinction is important for policy makers because irrational bubbles likely arises because of peculiar social-psychological phenomenon, which can be difficult or impossible to address with policy, while planners and policy makers can more tangibly address many factors associated with uncertainty bubbles. In the remained we focus on the extent to which the latter may be driving residential markets in Australia, and suggest a myriad of ways that public policy makers may decrease uncertainty. Figure 6: House Price Index for Homes, 1993-‐2010 25 Index 20 ADL Houses 15 BNE Houses 10 MEL Houses PER Houses 5 0 1993q1 SYD Houses 1996q1 1999q1 2002q1 2005q1 2008q1 Quarter Source: Residex Figure 7: House Price Index for Units, 1993-‐2010 25 Index 20 ADL Units 15 BNE Units 10 MEL Units PER Units 5 SYD Units 0 1993q1 1996q1 1999q1 2002q1 Quarter Source: Residex 2005q1 2008q1 Housing markets are inherently rife with uncertainty. This is because of “natural” inefficiencies that arise in both the demand and supply of housing (Mankiw, 1989; Case 1992; and Ortalo-Magné and Rady, 1999). As such, prices are volatile in the short-run, so we should expect a natural range of real house price fluctuations. These natural fluctuations result from asynchronous movements of demand and supply, but also exogenous (or sometime endogenous) changes in government policies. Thus, short-run uncertainty exists as to whether and when new supply can match increases in household demand. Households may respond to this supply uncertainty by more quickly purchasing homes in an attempt to preemptively avoid future unaffordability, and thus are more likely to bid and borrow higher amounts for housing than would otherwise occur with less uncertainty of supply. However, uncertainty also exists in government policy. In Australia, the major capital cities are dominated by a “plentitude, plethora, and plague” of land use regulations (Bunker, 2008; Hamnett and Kellett, 2007). These plans arguably increase uncertainty of the development process, as the development approval process can depend upon consent from a variety of government agencies. Furthermore, government interest in enforcement of the various planning policies waxes and wanes with different elected parties (Gleeson and Coiacetto, 2007). Thus, uncertainly arises not only because of “natural” asynchronous shifts in demand and supply, but also from rapid and often contradictory changes in federal, state, and local land use regulations. This uncertainty may ultimately reduce the long-term supply of new homes and lead to supply induced inflations of prices. (Mayer and Somerville, 2000). However, there is no reason to believe that all housing markets segments experience similar conditions simultaneously with respect to uncertainty. This is because the costs of the two primary components of residential property prices - land and construction – move independently from one another. Thus, housing types that utilize these inputs in different proportions would experience different price effects as each cost changes. For example, a restriction on land supply would disproportionally affect housing types that are land intensive, such as single-family detached dwellings. Recent evidence from McLaughlin (2011) suggests such policies may indeed reduce new single-family supply in Australian capital cities. On the other hand, the price effects on smaller, less land intensive multifamily units would be substantially lower. This latter point is perhaps heightened by concurrent adoption of policies designed to increase the supply of multifamily units. In Australia, adoption of policies promoting mixed-used medium density and transit oriented developments has been quite common, especially in states with metropolitan-wide land restrictions (Hamnett and Kellett, 2007). However with the emergence of groups such as Save Our Suburbs, local resistance to densification may greatly add to future uncertainty of the supply of both types of housing. Descriptive evidence of house prices suggests such differentiated price effects may be occurring in Australian cities as a result of the various land use policies. Figures 6 and 7 show the Residex capital city quarterly price index for houses and units between 1993 and 2010, respectively. While the general trend of price movements has been upward, especially for Sydney, Melbourne, and Brisbane, the trajectory has been much steeper for single-family homes than for multifamily units. With the exception of Adelaide, price appreciation of single-family homes has outpaced that of multifamily units. Thus, uncertainty bubbles, if they exist, are much more likely for detached dwellings, although the data suggests attached units have experienced similar, but less pronounced trajectories. To add credence to our argument that uncertainty may be driving a housing market bubble in Australia, the most recent empirical work on housing bubbles in Australia suggests only housing markets in Sydney and Perth experienced bubbles over the past 15 years (Jiang, Song, Liu, 2011). Using price deviations from predicted influences of economic fundamentals, the authors find prices in the many of the other cities – Melbourne, Brisbane, Hobart, and Canberra – were actually undervalued from 1995-2008, and that only prices in Adelaide and Darwin followed market fundamentals. Still, Australian households are experiencing higher levels of house price stress. Figure 8 displays the median multiple – which is the ratio of mdeian house price to median income - for Australian capital cities from 1981-2009. The story is essentially the same for each city: in the 1980s, median house prices ranged from approximately three to five times median incomes, but by 2009 the multiple range was between six and nine. Thus, even if most markets in Australia are not technically experiencing irrational bubbles, it is apparent that more than just increases in median incomes have been driving house price growth in Australian cities. Median Mul@ple Figure 8: Median Mul@ple for Australian Capital Ci@es 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Sydney Melbourne Brisbane Adelaide Perth Hobart 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 2006 Year Source: Demogrpahia, 2011; ABS, REIA 2009 Canberra Policy Recommendations and Concluding Comments The foregoing discussion suggests a range public policy reforms designed to reduce excessive oscillations in property prices and increase housing affordability, especially for lower income households. We identify four such arenas, starting with improved infrastructure management for both greenfields development and urban renewal. Rather than play catch-up most of the time, our cities need integrated and well-coordinated infrastructure supply in advance of anticipated population growth. In the interests of social equity, we advocate funding the necessary works on a city-wide basis using three-part tariffs that include a component for system extension in addition to those covering recurrent and maintenance costs. This should reduce dramatically the current user-pays charges levied against new residential allotments at the urban fringe and reducing the cost of housing for entry level home owners, the households least able to afford high land costs. This strategy should also accelerate regeneration of the existing urban fabric to higher residential densities. Our second reform agenda focuses on the culture of urban planning, which has become excessively th th concerned with regulatory minutiae and less so with the imaginative agendas of the 19 and early 20 centuries. One such task is to encourage and embolden developers and architects to invent new forms of entry level housing for currently disadvantaged groups, especially single-person, young, and low income households. Such developments are needed close to public transport nodes and major employment centres, whether CBD or regional, and individual units are likely to be small scale. That will not matter much if developments are amenity rich either on-site or in the immediate neighbourhood. We have no preference for either owner-occupier or rental accommodation. This kind of development is also crucial if our major cities are to accommodate within existing urban footprints a large proportion (perhaps 80%) of likely population increase over the next 40 years. Central to the second agenda, is the need to gain rapid community acceptance for innovative medium to high density urban forms. This undoubtedly means lessening the power of NIMBY sentiments, although still respecting people’s right to comment critically on proposed developments. There are few proposals that do not benefit from community consultation. We see two important strategies in this regard. First, obstructionist NIMBY sentiments are often assisted by local government fragmentation, whereby councillors, elected or those standing for office, are forced to pander to defensive community sentiment. The logical antidote is, of course, amalgamation of councils into larger units less amenable to local capture, and maybe a city the size of Sydney should have a maximum of 4 local government jurisdictions. Secondly, we advocate revising the power of heritage protection arrangements along the lines recommended by the Productivity Commission (2006). Parts of our cities have been placed off-limits to significant redevelopment, and often at unfair cost to existing residents. While acknowledging the importance retention of important heritage items to link society to inspirational elements of its past, we should actively facilitate future aspirations. The clash of the two will often require mutual compromise, which is sometimes difficult with existing provisions. Finally, we would like to see property ownership toppled from its position as Australia’s premier sporting event. This is cemented by a large raft of subsidies that privilege home ownership compared with other asset classes and these privileges, including the absence of Capital Gains Tax on owner-occupied housing (inflation adjusted) and Negative Gearing on rental housing, are hugely socially regressive. Most of the benefits accrue to the top one-third of households by income. Their removal, along with iniquitous first homeowner schemes, would go a long way to lopping our infatuation with home ownership and real estate assets more generally. Simultaneously, our ability as a nation to allocate housing resources appropriately to various stages in the human life cycle is compromised by the extraordinary costs, in terms of estate agent and legal fees or government stamp duties, of switching homes. Reductions in those fees and charges should increase the flexibility of Australia’s existing housing stock to meet demand. Another important reform would be to cap the typical mortgage repayment term to 25 years to (i) save households a lifetime of repayments and a mass of additional interest charges to banks or other financial institutions and (ii) stave off possible term increases to 35 or 40 years which is where we may be heading. What potentially stands in the way of this agenda? Well, the 70% of households currently owning real estate are likely to be irate at diminished opportunities for making a large tax-free capital gain on their home purchase. Worse still for them, our agenda could well increase their annual infrastructure charges, and mute NIMY protest opportunities against developments incompatible with their Weltanschauung. And the politicians who would have to amend laws and regulations would be inescapably captive to such interests, who have massively more electoral power than those marginalised by current arrangements. Nor would State Governments take kindly to losing the valuable source of non-GST income provided by stamp duties on the transfer of residential property. On the other hand, the Australian Government could generate a fiscal windfall from the extension of Capital Gains Tax to owner-occupied residences, though the complexities entailed in calculating gains would probably require only levying tax on properties valued above some threshold amount, perhaps AU$500,000. The elimination of Negative Gearing would be simpler to handle administratively, but liable to community antipathy of the kind accompanying an earlier attempt by the Hawke Government in 1985. So, it would be wise not hold our breath for too long awaiting the outcomes we advocate. It looks like reform is only possible at the margin, so entrenched is the religion of owner-occupied housing in Australian society. References Bunker, R. (2008). A Plenitude, Plethora or Plague of Plans? State Strategic Plans, Metropolitan Strategies and Infrastructure Plans. Built Environment, 34(3): 319-332. Case, K.E. (1992). The Real Estate Cycle and the Economy: Consequences of the Massachusetts Boom of 1984-87. Urban Studies, 29(2): 171-183. Case, K.E. and Shiller, R.J. (2003). Is there a Bubble in the Housing Market? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 299-362. Demographia (2011), International Housing Affordability Survey, 7th edition, http://www.demographia.com (accessed 20 July 2011). Economist, The (2010) Global House Prices: Froth and Stagnation, 8 July. http://www.economist.com/node/16542826 (accessed 20 July 2011). Gleeson, B., & Coiacetto, E. (2007). Positive planning in Australia: A review of historical and emergent rationales. Urban Policy and Research, 25(1), 5-19. Hamnett S, & Kellett J. (2007). Onward, Outward, Upward? A Review of Contemporary Australian Metropolitan Growth Policies. Third State of Australian Cities Conference, Adelaide, February 18-20. Himmelberg, C, Mayer, C and Sinai, T. (2005). Assessing High House Prices: Bubbles, Fundamentals and Misperceptions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4): 67-92. Hirsch, Fred. (1977), The Social Limits to Growth, Routledge & Kegan Paul, London. Jiang, H., Song, Y., and Liu, C. (2011). House Price Bubble Estimations In Australia’s Capital Cities With Market Fundamentals. Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, 17(1): 132 – 156. Mankiw, N.G. (1989). The Baby Boom, the Baby Bust, and the Housing Cycle. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 19(2): 235-258. Mayer, C. J., & Somerville, C. T. (2000). Residential construction: Using the urban growth model to estimate housing supply. Journal of Urban Economics, 48(1), 85-109. Ortalo-Magné, F. and Rady, S. (1999). Boom in, bust out: Young Households and the Housing Price Cycle. European Economic Review, 43: 755-766. Shiller, R.J. (2008).The Subprime Solution: How Today's Global Financial Crisis Happened, and What to Do about It. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. Tony Sorensen (2011), Quantum Dreaming: the relevance of Quantum Mechanics to Regional Science, Australasian Journal of Regional Studies, 17(1): 81-100. Stiglitz, J.E. (1990). Symposium of Bubbles. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(2): 13-18.