Financial and Non-Financial Impact on Employees and Engineering Companies in Pune
Transcription
Financial and Non-Financial Impact on Employees and Engineering Companies in Pune
Financial and Non-Financial Impact on Employees and Employers of VRS Schemes offered by Large Scale Engineering Companies in Pune 1. Introduction “… if we feel need of machines, we certainly will have them. Every machine that helps every individual has a place, but there should be no place for machines that concentrate power in a few hands and turn the masses into mere machine minders, if indeed they do not make them unemployed…” Mahatma Gandhi 1.1 Voluntary Retirement Schemes (VRS) 1.1.1 Voluntary retirement schemes have now come to stay as a part of policy of the Government of India, the public and the private sectors. Even the protests of the Left political parties in India, to these schemes, have remained vocal and feeble. Industrialists propagate and implement them; economists advocate them and social thinkers meekly accept them. The Government Policy can be described as „willing to wound but afraid to hurt‟. Thus it has so far refrained from making the desired changes in the labour laws, but opened an escape route by making suitable provisions in the Income Tax Act, 1961. Voluntary retirement schemes are now seen as a panacea for increasing competitiveness, extending markets and accelerated economic growth. 1.1.2 The eighties of the last century saw disintegration of socialist economies, disillusionment with the public sector in mixed economies, disequilibrium in the balance of payments of several developing countries, and the desire of the capitalist economies to penetrate the markets of populous developing countries such as India, China, Indonesia in the context of slow growth and limited potential in their traditional markets. These developments ushered in the winds of change 1 in international thinking. The world was suddenly seen as a global village in the context of technological progress. This change in thinking necessitated a number of steps at the national and international level, which include, inter alia, reduction of trade barriers so as to permit free flow of goods across national frontiers; creation of environment in which free flow of capital can take place among nations; creation of environment permitting free flow of technology and creation of an environment in which free movement of labour can take place in different countries. 1.1.3 As these steps came to be implemented by the international agencies and fora, the governments and trans-national companies, the heat of competition and the need for technological upgradation came to be felt by the Indian industry. This in turn called for rationalization, restructuring and downsizing, a euphemism for labour retrenchment. The past did not hang so heavily on the shoulders of other countries in the world as it did in India. They were therefore willing and ready to implement the changes. They also found support and encouragement from international agencies. The World Development Report, 1995 observes as follows, “Major transformations are associated with massive employment restructuring – many jobs may be destroyed and many new ones created. Such hires and separations increase dramatically during periods of major change creating turmoil in labour market and uncertainty for workers.” 1.1.4 There was however no great turmoil, agitation or militancy in the Indian Labour Market. May be there was only a whimper. Tushar K. Mahanti observes in his study Uncertain future makes labourers avoid disputes, opt for VRS as follows, “Indian labourers known for their militancy and their penchant to stop work on the slightest pretext have begun to avoid work stoppages of late... But the question is: what made this attitudinal transformation possible? The answer is, The fear of uncertain future. This has made labourers wiser and they are now opting for separation 2 schemes rather than going for work stoppages, lest they might lose their jobs as well as the financial benefits offered to them.” (Economic Times, 07.04.2003). 1.1.5 This factual position has led the Report of the Special Group on Targeting Ten Million Employment opportunities per year headed by Shri S.P. Gupta to observe in 2002 as follows, “The case for encouraging the growth of the organized sector is certainly supported by its capacity to invest in major infrastructure, (in most cases they are capital intensive) to give support systems to the rest of the economy; but for the generation of employment, their growth cannot be regarded as the answer… given the fact that the organized sector (especially the public sector) is already carrying excess labour, the immediate effect will be more of firing than hiring.” Voluntary Retirement Schemes have thus not only come to stay, but will also be quite alive and kicking in the future. 1.2 Special Features of VRS 1.2.1 Voluntary retirement concept is not something new, introduced only in the wake of economic reforms since nineties. The Central as well as almost all the State Government Service Rules had and have the provisions for voluntary retirement. But the response to these provisions has never been massive, as it has been to VRS. It has been normal and employees have been retiring voluntarily only in exceptional circumstances. They were not and are never induced to retire. There is no doubt provision for compulsory retirement. But it is a penal provision evoked only in exceptional circumstances. There has never been the fear of uncertain future. No special incentives are also attached to voluntary retirement. The response is therefore natural and normal. 1.2.2 In contrast, the voluntary retirement schemes introduced and implemented in the era of economic reforms and at present as well, invariably provide inducements to retire. Often these inducements are perceived to be attractive. But it is not only the bait of inducements that prompt 3 employees to „volunteer‟ retirement. It is the fear of uncertain future and the possible loss of financial benefits associated with inducements, which explains the observed response to voluntary retirement schemes. 1.2.3 Secondly, voluntary retirement schemes are not on tap as part and parcel of the normal service rules in the public or the private sector. It is only when an undertaking is convinced of the need to restructure, rationalize or downsize in the interest of survival and growth that proposals for voluntary retirement schemes are offered. Even such proposals cannot be offered by many undertakings which do not have the financial capacity to pay such incentives. It is also not that only technological upgradation that calls for VRS. Past over-staffing, flab, competition from the small-scale sector or imports also necessitate introduction of VRS. 1.2.4 But then why VRS and not simple retrenchment? Unlike other developed and developing countries where the labour laws are not restrictive and allow relatively smooth process of retrenchment, the labour laws in India make it almost impossible to implement retrenchment selectively and timely. Political compulsions have prevented suitable amendments to the existing labour laws. The politicians and the bureaucrats have therefore been ingenious to open a bye-lane where the highway is blocked. They have thus made suitable provisions in the Income Tax Act, 1961 to enable undertakings to formulate relatively attractive VR Schemes. The package of attractive financial benefits coupled with significant income-tax relief lures the employees to opt for the offered VRS. 1.2.5 Thus there is no uncertain future, redundancy or financial incentives in natural and normal voluntary retirement, while all these three factors are the vital components of offered VRS. Normal voluntary retirement is a one-sided volition. VRS is in a way – mutual understanding apparently beneficial to both parties. Finally voluntary retirement either in the normal course or under VRS need not be and is often not superannuation. Normally retirement and 4 superannuation carry the same meaning to most people. In most cases retirement under VRS happens to be premature, when the normal commitments towards family and children are not over, and the physically and mentally alert and fit retiree has to have his time gainfully occupied. Idleness, empty mind and reduced income and financial status can have economic, social and moral implications. These conditions require to be carefully studied. 1.3 VRS and the Employer 1.3.1 The Employer is an active agent and initiator in any voluntary retirement scheme he introduces. He is only a respondent in respect of resignation, normal voluntary retirement or superannuation. The initiative behind VRS enhances the responsibility of the employer, both in his and workers' interest. Reducing the flab or overstaffing through VRS is an admission of miscalculation carrying a price-tag. There is a dislocation in the systems, working and work-culture where VRS is implemented. The impact on the remaining workers may affect the working and the atmosphere in the undertaking. In the event of technological upgradation, employment of new highly skilled/qualified staff or training of existing staff has to be carefully planned and funded. It is often said that for an employer „labour‟ is simply an item of cost to be reduced to a minimum, if it cannot be eliminated altogether by automation etc. 1.3.2 The employer however lives in a society and is part of the social and moral ethos. VRS may be a business necessity. But it has also social and human aspects associated with it. There is an increased awareness about the social responsibility of business. VRS may affect industrial relations as well. Besides, if there is no proper planning and calculation before introducing VRS, the very objectives behind VRS may go haywire, and profitability and competitiveness may not improve. 1.3.3. The employer is normally aware of the consequences of introducing VRS in his undertaking since it involves his self-interest. He can also obtain 5 expert advice. But the expectations from implementation of VRS may not materialize because of external factors, such as market conditions, imports and competition in respect of the use of latest technology. It is only in retrospect and careful studies of undertakings that the implications of implementation of VRS can be adequately known. It has been reported that even in countries where downsizing or retrenchment can be effected with relative ease, the results of downsizing have not been according to expectations. On the other hand downsizing is reported to have yielded the desired benefits in some cases. It may be also that because of different conditions prevailing in different regions, different undertakings and different product markets, no generalizations can be made in respect of the impact of VRS on the employers. It should however be possible to undertake industry-wise and regionwise studies to study the impact. Such studies would be definitely useful for considering VRS proposals and effecting policy modifications. 1.4 Statutory Provisions 1.4.1 As stated above, the most important feature of the VR Schemes is the incentives they offer and the tax concessions available under the Income Tax Act, 1961. No tax concessions were available before 1987 when Section 10 (10c) was inserted in the Income Tax Act, 1961 to provide tax relief to retiring employees who took voluntary retirement in accordance with the VR Scheme duly approved by the Central Govt. The provisions of Section 10(10c) became effective from 1.4.1987 and were applicable only to the employees of public sector companies. For employees of private sector undertakings/companies, those provisions were extended only from 1.4.1992. The VR Schemes of the private sector companies have to be in accordance with the guidelines prescribed by the Government in this behalf. Further, their VR Schemes have to be approved by the Chief Commissioner of Income Tax. The VR Scheme of any private sector company must meet the following requirements, mentioned in the guidelines. 6 1. It should apply to an employee who has completed 10 years of service or completed 40 years of age. 2. It should apply to all employees excepting the Directors of the company. 3. It should result in overall reduction in the existing strength of employees. 4. The vacancy caused by the voluntary retirement should not be filled up. 5. The retiring employee should not be employed in another company or concern belonging to the same management. 6. The amount receivable on account of voluntary retirement of the employee does not exceed the amount equivalent to three months' salary for each completed year of service, or salary at the time of retirement multiplied by the balance months of service left before the date of retirement on superannuation of the employee. In any case, the amount should not exceed Rs. Five lakh in case of each employee. The amount representing the excess above Rs. Five lakh is taxable. 1.4.2 The companies can frame different schemes of voluntary retirement for different classes of their employees. But they have to conform to the above guidelines. The guidelines also include the criteria of economic viability. It has been clarified that this requirement in the guidelines, which reflects the economic criterion, is to the effect that the scheme of voluntary retirement has been drawn to result in overall reduction in the existing strength of employees of the company. The schemes can be drawn by loss making as well as profit making companies. It should be noted that an employee taking up voluntary retirement in normal course, such as government servants, does not get the benefits under these provisions. The benefits are available only if he opts for voluntary retirement under a voluntary retirement scheme applicable to 7 him, drawn up by the employer and approved by the Chief Income Tax Commissioner. 1.5 Causes and Extent of Surplus Manpower 1.5.1 The phenomenon of large-scale reduction in manpower through the implementation of voluntary retirement can not be viewed in isolation. It has to be seen in the context of economic policies in the past, the developing economic situation since the late eighties in the last century, the economic reforms introduced in nineties, opening up of the economy through liberal import policy, progress in technology in general and information technology in particular and competition both domestic and external. 1.5.2 The industrial and trade policies pursued by the Government for over four decades since Independence provided heavy protection to Indian Industry. It had a captive domestic market because of highly restrictive import policies. The accelerated growth of public sector, efforts for import substitution and lack of competition helped the Indian industry to grow without technology and market constraints. The only major difficulties it faced were with reference to industrial licensing policy, foreign exchange regulation, M.R.T.P. Act and labour legislation. It could get over most of these problems because of market demand and the compulsions of economic growth of the country. Labour legislation gave protection to the labour whose strength and militancy continued to rise. The work-culture and the overall industrial culture reflected relative disregard towards efficiency, higher productivity and discipline. Yet the industry could thrive till the winds of change began to blow since eighties. 1.5.3 During the eighties it became clear that the Indian public sector could not come up to the high expectations from it. Low rate of return on investment, declining contribution to nation's exchequer and low capacity utilization became common features of the public sector working. Delays, cost overruns and wastage of scarce resources became common. The public sector was dominated by bureaucracy and politicians lacking 8 business acumen and vision, and neglect of manpower planning. There had to be a rethinking about the pampering of the public sector. This realization came to the young and dynamic Prime Minister, Shri Rajiv Gandhi, in 1984. He declared in a broadcast that the public sector had spread into too many areas where it should not be. He declared his resolve to develop the public sector only to undertake jobs which the private sector could not do and to provide further openings to the private sector to help its expansion in the interest of free growth of economy. This rethinking about the public sector was not confined to India. The disillusionment witnessed in the eighties in socialist economies, the disintegration of the Soviet Union, the rise of European Common Market and the trend towards dismantling trade barriers led to a close review of the public sector in the mixed capital enterprise systems the world over. The seeds for privatization were sown in this transitory phase. 1.5.4 But the private sector was also not the epitome of productivity and efficiency. The post WTO decisions revealed its shortcomings. It had ceased to be competitive and cost-conscious. Sluggish market conditions, changes in consumers‟ tastes and preferences and technological obsolescence compounded its problems. 1.5.5 The political developments in the context of the decline of Indian National Congress threatened the stability of governments at the Centre. The populism, lack of fiscal discipline and mismanagement of the economy by successive Governments in eighties led to a deep economic crisis. India faced a serious balance of payments crisis as the eighties came to a close. Foreign exchange reserves dipped to just Rs. 1,500 crore in January 1991, and the Government was forced to sell 20 tonnes of gold in the international market and pledge another 27 tonnes to the Bank of England. The rupee had to be devalued. In addition India was forced to approach the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund for a loan of about seven billion dollars to overcome the crisis. These 9 institutions did provide help but they insisted on appropriate economic reforms to bring the economy back on rails. To ensure the reforms, some stringent conditions were imposed which were known as conditionality clauses. But these were considered necessary by the World Bank and IMF for bringing about balance of payments equilibrium externally and to reduce fiscal deficits and check inflation internally. Privatisation, opening up of the Indian market, free flow of capital, technology and goods had therefore to be the main ingredients of the reforms that were brought about willy-nilly in 1991. It is a moot point whether the government committed to the socialistic pattern of society since Independence, would ever have thought of such reforms in the absence of economic crisis and consequent pressure from international agencies and developed countries. Privatisation and disinvestment became necessary to ensure fiscal discipline. Closure of loss making public sector units and retrenchment where overstaffing had become a norm and disinvestment were thus part of the economic reforms. But hard decisions are not palatable to policy makers who are used to always opt for the soft side of the equation. Privatisation and disinvestment policies have therefore been half-hearted or bogged down in controversies. Retrenchment was not economically as well politically feasible. Stringent labour laws could not be touched. The offshoot was the clever voluntary retirement scheme through amendments to the Income Tax Act, 1961. Excess manpower was discovered and identified only in the context of compulsive economic reforms. 1.5.6 When the public sector started reducing its fat and shedding manpower, could the private sector be far behind? There was a clamour for extending the provision of Section 10(10c) of Income Tax Act, 1961 to the private sector as well and the demand was graciously accepted. This was a logical corollary of the New Industrial Policy announced in July 1991. 10 1.5.7 The new Industrial Policy set the following aims: 1. Unshackling the Indian industrial economy from the cobwebs of unnecessary bureaucratic control, 2. Introducing liberalization with a view to integrate the Indian economy with the world economy, 3. Removing restrictions on direct foreign investment as also freeing the domestic entrepreneur from restrictions of M.R.T.P. Act, and 4. Shedding the load of the public enterprises which have shown a very low rate of return or were consistently incurring losses. 1.5.8 The Industrial Licensing Policy also underwent appropriate changes consistent with those in the Industrial Policy. Industrial licensing was abolished for all projects except for a short list of industries related to security and strategic concerns, social reasons, hazardous chemicals, overriding environmental reasons and items of elitist consumption. Existing reservations for small-scale sector would continue. There would be automatic approval for technology agreements related to high priority industries. Approvals for direct foreign investment up to 51 per cent foreign equity would be accorded to high priority industries. The policy tries to facilitate foreign direct investment in infrastructure, core, priority, export oriented industries and establish linkages with farming sector. 1.5.9 The obvious result of the economic reforms policy, industrial policy and industrial licensing policy was a review of the manpower both in public and private sector, increasing the competitiveness and profitability of industrial undertakings and introduction of modern technology. Some broad studies were made to estimate the excess or redundant manpower in both public and private sector in the light of these policies. Prof T.S. Papola writes in his study Structural Adjustment, Labour Market Flexibility and Employment, on the basis of the data on industrial sickness available with the financial institutions, “It was estimated that closure of chronically sick enterprises in the Central Public 11 Sector would involve redundancy of about 4 lakh workers. Similar estimates in case of large and medium private sector enterprises were at around 5 lakh.”1 These estimates were only about redundancy in chronically sick units. Sudipto Mundle studied the redundancy of workforce due to restructuring and closure of both Central and State Public Enterprises and quasi-government organizations in the coming three years and arrived at an estimate of 11 lakh employees. For the private sector his estimate was 13 lakh employees.2 This study has been referred to by Prof. T.S. Papola in his own study cited above. Assuming the same level of 18 per cent redundancy in government employment which Sudipto Mundle assumed, Business Today estimated a surplus of 18 lakh employees among the ten million government employees including administrative staff and workers in departmental undertakings such as the railways, telecom etc. According to Pramod Verma, even without technological change, it should be possible to reduce labour by 5 to 7 per cent, which meant between 13 lakh and 18 lakh persons; and if technology was upgraded, the organized sector would have another 25 lakh surplus staff. Ruddar Dutt estimated a surplus of about 25 to 30 per cent in public sector undertakings.3 The Government of India itself finalized a scheme envisaging rationalization of about 20 per cent of the 23 lakh employees in 246 central public sector undertakings. This works out to about 4.5 lakh persons.4 The National Textile Corporation visualized retirement of 75000 employees, and the Steel Authority of 1 T.S. Papola, „Structural Adjustment, Labour Market Flexibility and Employment‟, The Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Vol. XXXVI No.1, 1994 2 Sudipto Mundle, Structural Adjustment – Employment and Redundancy in the Organized Sector, ILO-ARTEP [mimeo] New Delhi, 1993 3 Ruddar Dutt, „New Economic Policy and its impact on Industrial Relations and Employment in India‟, The Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Vol. XXXVI No. 1, March 1993 4 Ratan Khasnabis, Sudipti Banerjee, „Political Economy of Voluntary Retirement‟, Economic and Political Weekly, 28.12.1996 12 India 16900 employees. But a study of Mritunjaya Athreya conducted earlier in 1987 revealed a surplus of 80,000 employees in the Steel Authority of India. The surplus in Coal India was estimated at 50,000 employees. About 50 per cent of the employees of the State Road Transport Undertakings were estimated surplus. The same estimate might apply to the State Electricity Boards. 1.5.10 The use of obsolete technology is also stated to be the reason for surplus labour and high labour costs, resulting in high production costs. The case of the dying textile industries is very well known. In the steel industry it takes TISCO two days to produce one tonne of steel while in South Korean steel industry it takes only eleven hours for the same output. Within the country, with modern technology, Gujarat Ambuja produces 2000 tonnes cement per worker while with outdated technology ACC produces only 475 tonnes cement per worker. 1.5.11 It will thus be seen that in the early climate of globalization India faced a serious balance of payment crisis which led to seeking assistance from International Agencies. This assistance was offered subject to implementing economic reforms and fiscal discipline because of pressure from developed countries. The conditions imposed by international agencies included opening up of the economy through import liberalization, foreign investment, privatization and liberalization of industrial policy in favour of the private sector. Privatisation necessitated closure of loss making public sector undertakings and restructuring of inefficiently run public sector units not giving expected rate of return on investment. This required large-scale retrenchment of surplus labour, which the existing labour laws did not permit. There was a lack of will to implement amendment to labour laws due to political compulsions. A way was therefore found out to effect reduction in surplus labour by suitably amending the Income Tax Act, 1961 and providing tax-relief and incentives through schemes of voluntary 13 retirement in public sector units. The private sector also faced competition due to import liberalization, foreign investment and use of outdated technology. Restructuring of private sector units as well became necessary. The provisions of the amended Income Tax Act, 1961 were therefore made applicable to private sector also in due course. This resulted in implementing voluntary retirement schemes on a large scale in the private sector also. Estimates have varied from 4.5 lakh to 25 lakh of the surplus labour in both public and private sectors. On a high side this came almost to 20 per cent of the existing staff in the organized sector, public as well as private. 1.6 Extent of Reduction in Manpower 1.6.1 According to the annual reports of the Ministry of Labour, Government of India, the number of workers taking VRS with assistance from National Renewal Fund was, 75,004 during 1992 and 1995. M.V. Srinivasan in his article in the, Economic and Political Weekly dated 10.7.1999 writes that according to Ministry of Industry, only 1.18 lakh workers opted for VRS till 1999. He also refers to the media claims that 2.18 lakh workers in the Central PSUs had opted for VRS till 1999. The extent of reduction in public sector banks is however accurately known. Between 2000-01, 101,300 employees or 11.7 per cent of the total staff opted for retirement from public sector banks. The number of companies offering VRS rose from 100 in 1996-97 to 296 in 2000-01 and 366 in 2002-03 (out of a sample of 3,795 companies) according to a study published in Economic Times dated 7.4.2003. While it is now well known that the number of companies offering VRS is on the rise in private sector, company-wise data about the total strength of employees, employees taking VRS, and the nature of rehabilitation efforts is difficult to come by. 1.6.2 The impact of reduction in manpower through VRS in the public and private sectors can however be known, albeit indirectly from the data 14 relating to organized sector employment which is regularly published officially. It reflects not only the number of employees taking up VRS but also the numbers relating to normal retirements, resignations, terminations, new recruitments, privatization etc. It is expected that in a growing economy, employment in the organized sector should show a rising trend from year to year. This has been the case in our country as well. The organized sector employment in India rose from 121 lakh in 1960-61 to 175 lakh in 1970-71, to 229 lakh in 1980-81 and 267 lakh in 1990-91. In the wake of incentives and tax relief provided to retirees in public and private sectors in the nineties and the rising number of companies offering VRS since late nineties, the rising trend has been reversed. The employment in the organized sector rose to a peak of 282.45 lakh in 1997 and has been going down consistently since then. Table No. 1.1 Employment in the Organized Sector Lakh persons as on 31st March Year Public Sector Private Sector Total Organized Sector 1981 154.84 73.95 228.79 1991 190.57 76.76 267.33 1995 194.66 80.59 275.35 1996 194.29 85.12 279.41 1997 195.59 86.86 282.45 1998 194.18 87.48 281.66 1999 194.15 86.98 281.13 2000 193.14 86.46 279.60 2001 191.38 86.52 277.89 2002 187.73 84.32 272.06 2003 185.80 84.21 270.00 Source : The Economic Survey, 2004-05, Ministry of Labour, D.G. E and T. Public sector employment rose to a peak of 195.59 lakh in 1997 but came down to 185.80 lakh in 2003 showing a fall of 9.79 lakh or almost 15 a million. The private sector employment reached a peak of 87.48 lakh in 1998 but came down to 84.21 lakh in 2003 showing a fall of 3.27 lakh. Total organized sector employment peaked to 282.45 lakh in 1997 but came down to 270 lakh in 2003 showing a fall of 12.45 lakh or 4.4 per cent. The fall was steeper at 5.0 per cent in public sector. It was 4.0 per cent in private sector. (The details are given in Table No. 1.1). If we consider the estimates of surplus manpower referred to above, even this all-inclusive decline in organized sector is less than 50 per cent of the estimates if we take into consideration the rise up to 1997 after the estimates were made. The reduction in surplus manpower through VRS may therefore continue on a larger scale in the coming years. 1.6.3 The decline in employment in the organized sector is not however accompanied by decline in national income. National income shows a positive growth rate against the negative growth rate in organized sector employment as will be seen from Table No. 1.2. It is a moot point whether the implementation of VRS on a large scale in both public and private sectors is a contributory factor in the growth of economy. It is seen that contrary to the observations of the World Development Report 1995 that in the process of massive employment restructuring many new jobs would be created, there is a massive reduction in organized sector employment. It needs to be examined whether the overall employment in the organized as well unorganized sectors has increased in the wake of new economic policy; whether unemployment has come down; whether the contribution of the organized sector to the gross domestic product has registered an increase after the implementation of VRS; and the overall effect has been beneficial to both employers and the employees. Such reviews and evaluations need to be undertaken by the Government as well as representative bodies of the industry as also by other nongovernment organizations. Their results should be given wide publicity from time to time to help mid-course corrections wherever necessary. 16 Table No. 1.2 Variations in National Income and Organized Sector Employment Per cent change over previous year Year GDP at Factor Cost at Constant Prices Per Capita GDP at Organized Sector Employment Constant Prices Total Public Private Sector Sector 1996-97 7.8 5.4 1.1 0.7 2.0 1997-98 4.8 2.5 (-) 0.2 (-) 0.7 0.7 1998-99 6.5 3.9 (-) 0.2 0.0 (-) 0.6 1999-00 6.1 5.2 (-) 0.5 (-) 0.5 (-) 0.6 2000-01 4.4 2.1 (-) 0.6 (-) 0.9 0.1 2001-02 5.8 3.3 (-) 2.1 (-) 1.9 (-) 2.5 2002-03 4.0 2.3 (-) 0.8 (-) 1.0 (-) 0.1 Source : Compiled from data published in the Economic Survey 2004-05 1.6.4 The VRS phenomenon is confined to the organized sector only. This sector employs highly qualified, skilled and experienced manpower. The massive strength of academically and technically qualified manpower in our country needs to be gainfully employed or self-employed. Premature retirement of such manpower employed in the organized sector is bound to have economic, social, financial, familial, moral and other behavioural consequences. 1.6.5 Ours is a highly populous country. The burgeoning population needs not only to be fed but also gainfully employed to feed itself and contribute to the country's development and prosperity. As Mahatma Gandhi has emphasized, the poor of the world cannot be helped by mass production, but only by production by the masses. In singing praise of modern technology and vying to make use of it, are we losing sight of the crores of poor, unemployed and underemployed masses in the country? They constitute our backbone. As E.F. Schumacher has observed, there is a universal agreement that a fundamental source of wealth is human labour. In a country, which abounds in manpower, the primary 17 consideration cannot be to maximize output per man, it must be to maximize work opportunities for the unemployed and underemployed. The Common Minimum Programme of the United Progressive Alliance (UPA) (which came in power at the Centre in 2004) observes as follows, “The U.P.A. reiterates its abiding commitment to economic reforms with a human face, (emphasis added) that stimulates growth, investment and employment ... The UPA rejects the idea of automatic hire and fire.” Yet the report of the Special Group appointed by the Planning Commission, on targeting ten million employment opportunities per year observes, ... “Given the fact that the organized sector (especially the public sector) is already carrying excess labour, the immediate effect will be more of firing than hiring.” 1.7 Need for In Depth Studies and the Present Study 1.7.1 The Voluntary Retirement Schemes both in public and private sectors cannot be viewed in isolation. Various policy announcements of the Government, the actual pace and nature of implementation, the vision and views of the private sector, their requirements, the nature of various VR Schemes, the impact of these schemes on the concerned units, employers, employees, industry and economy need to be studied by various institutions and individuals in depth. This study is therefore a small part of many such studies required to be undertaken. Due to constraints of time, funds, manpower etc. it is limited to the financial and non-financial impact on employers and employees of VR Schemes offered by large-scale engineering companies in Pune metropolis. It is felt that such industry-wise, region-wise micro level studies would also help in bringing into sharp focus the specificities of individual industries and regions and provide insights for policy making and implementation both at macro and micro levels. 18 1.8 Pune Metropolitan Region 1.8.1 The locale selected for this study is the Pune Metropolitan Region. For one, the region is selected because most of the industrial development in Pune has taken place only after the formation of Maharashtra State in the sixties of the last century. For another Pune has a long reputation of being a premier educational and cultural centre not only of Maharashtra, but also of India. There are scores of professional, educational, management and research institutions, a regular university and over half a dozen deemed universities in Pune. This ensures an abundant supply of skilled, educated and technical professional manpower to industry. In recent years Pune has become a hub of I.T. industry and soon it is likely to surpass Bangalore and Hyderabad in IT Sector. Thirdly, Pune has good medical, health and other infrastructure facilities of water, power, transport, communication etc. There is a large defence establishment, the premier defence academy as also defence education and training establishments in the city. The city has a very pleasant climate and is endowed with the bounty of nature in its environs. It is also active and vibrant politically and socially. Among the 35 mega cities with a population of over one million in India, Pune ranks eighth. It has recorded fourth highest population growth rate between 1991 and 2001 among 13 major cities in the country as will be seen from Table No. 1.3. According to the Industrial and Commercial Directory of Pune, 2002 published by the Mahratta Chamber of Commerce, Industries and Agriculture, Pune, the number of permanent and provisional industrial units registered with the Joint Director of Industries, Pune, was 48,189 and 13,150, respectively. The number of registered working factories as on December, 1999 was 3,394, a little more than 10 per cent of the 33,626 registered working factories in Maharashtra. The city industry is therefore quite sensitive to changes in Industrial policy, licensing policy and industrial competition. This makes it one of the ideal locations to study the impact of VR 19 Schemes implemented during the last decade. Finally, the researcher is based in Pune, familiar with Pune and has relatively easy access to industrial units and employees. Hence the choice of Pune for this study. Table No. 1.3 Population of Cities with a Population of One Million and above Sr. No. Name of City Population 1991 (in Million) Population 2001 (in Million) Ten Yearly Increase Per cent 1. Greater Mumbai 12.6 16.4 30.2 2. Kolkata 10.9 13.2 21.1 3. Delhi 8.4 12.8 52.4 4. Chennai 5.4 6.4 18.5 5. Bangalore 4.1 5.7 39.0 6. Hyderabad 4.3 5.5 27.9 7. Ahmedabad 3.3 4.5 36.4 8. Pune 2.5 3.7 48.0 9. Surat 1.5 2.8 86.6 10. Kanpur 2.1 2.7 28.5 11. Lucknow 1.6 2.2 37.5 12. Jaipur 1.5 2.3 53.3 13. Nagpur 1.7 2.1 23.5 Source: Registrar General of India. 1.8.2 Pune district is one of the most prominent districts in Maharashtra as will be seen from Annexure No. 1.1 to this chapter. (The Annexure No. 1.1 gives data on important indicators for Pune District and Maharashtra for ready comparison.) According to the alphabetical list of manufacturing companies published in the Industrial and Commercial Directory of Pune 2002, there were 4,950 manufacturing units in Pune District. There were 163 units having Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and 198 ISO 9000 and QS 9000 certified units in Pune district. Over 90 per cent of all these units were located in Pune Metropolitan Region. 20 The industrial units in this region are mostly located in PimpriChinchwad-Bhosari Complex, Dapodi, Bopodi, Khadki, Hadapsar, Kothrud, and Gultekdi etc. The region consists of area under the jurisdiction of Pune Municipal Corporation, Pimpri-Chinchwad Municipal Corporation, Pune Cantonment Board, Khadki Cantonment Board and Dehu Road Cantonment Board. There is no language problem in Pune as besides Marathi, Gujarati and English, Hindi is also spoken and understood by most of the local population. As a result of the influx of students and workers from other States the city is fast progressing towards a cosmopolitan character. 1.9 Chapter Scheme 1.9.1 The chapter scheme for the presentation of this study is as follows: Chapter 1 Introduction Chapter 2 Significance and Importance of the Study Chapter 3 The Impact of Economic Reforms : A Review Chapter 4 Theoretical Background and Review of Literature Chapter 5 Analytical Framework Chapter 6 Voluntary Retirement Schemes Chapter 7 Presentation and Analysis of Data-I Chapter 8 Presentation and Analysis of Data-II Chapter 9 Presentation and Analysis of Data-III and Testing of Hypotheses Chapter 10 Conclusions and Scope for Further Research Bibliography 21 Annexure No. 1.1 Pune District at Glance Sr. No. 1. 2. Items Unit Pune District Maharashtra 1705‟-1902‟ 1604‟-2201‟ E 7302‟-7501‟ 7206‟-8009‟ Sq.km. 15,642 307,713 Location 1.1 Latitude 0 1.2 East Longitude 0 N Area and Population (1991 Census) 2.1 Area 2.2 Towns No. 34 336 2.3 Villages No. 1,862 43,027 i. Inhabited No. 1,844 40,412 ii. Un-inhabited No. 18 2,615 2.4 Rural Population in 000 2725 48,396 2.5 Urban Population in 000 2807 30,542 2.6 Total Population in 000 5532 78,938 2.7 Scheduled Caste People in 000 631 8,758 2.8 Scheduled Tribe People in 000 216 7,318 2.9 Male in 000 2,861 40,826 2.10 Female in 000 2,671 38,112 2.11 Sex Ratio : Female per 1000 Males 933 934 Person per sq.km. 354 257 2.12 Density of Population 2.13 Total Workers 2.14 1 As Cultivators and Agri. Labours in 000 2051 n.a. 2 Others in 000 179 n.a. 3 Non-Workers in 000 1854 n.a. Literacy i. Total per cent 71.05 64.87 ii. Male per cent 81.56 76.58 iii. Female per cent 59.77 52.32 Continued 22 Annexure No. 1.1 Continued Pune District at Glance Sr. No. 3. Items Maximum (Absolute) 0 Celsius 38.6 47.7 ii. Minimum 0 Celsius 9.1 2.4 iii. Pune Rainfall mm 992.29 1292.53 Agriculture 4.1 Cultivatable Area „000 ha 1115 23178 4.2 Area Not Available for Cultivation „000 ha 167 2914 4.3 Area Sown 4.4 6. Net „000 ha 1016 17732 ii. Gross „000 ha 1259 22166 Area Irrigated i. Net „000 ha 225 2568 ii. Gross „000 ha 278 3874 Area Under Forest 000 ha 171 5370 4.6 Land Revenue Collection Rs. lakh 82 7116 Actuals (99-2000) Rs. lakh 326.09 9200 Animal Husbandry (1997) 5.1 Live Stock „000 2424 39793 5.2 Cattle „000 896 17949 5.3 Buffaloes „000 286 8484 5.4 Sheeps and Goats „000 1198 14716 5.5 Poultry „000 3935 34984 No. 3394 33626 No. 1896 39413 No. 15787 152745 Industries (as on Dec. 1999) Working Factories (Regd) Electricity (as on 31.3.2000) 7.1 8. i. 4.5 6.1 7. Maharashtra Temperature i. 5. Pune District Climate (1999) 3.1 4. Unit Towns and villages Electrified Co-operation (1999-2000) 8.1 Co-operative Societies (all types) Continued 23 Annexure No. 1.1 Continued Pune District at Glance Sr. No. 9. Items Unit Pune District Maharashtra Medical and Public Health (1999-2000) 9.1 Hospitals No. 38 887 9.2 Primary Health Centers No. 90 1782 No. 4230 65338 10. Education (as in 1998-99) 10.1 10.2 10.3 Primary Education i. Institutions ii. Students „000 No. 793 12232 iii. Teachers „000 No. 21 314 No. 883 14918 Secondary Education (1998-99) i. Institutions ii. Students „000 No. 590 8748 iii. Teachers „000 No. 18 240 No. 104 1541 in 000 112 928 Higher Education (1998-99) i. Institutions ii. Students 11. Transport and Communication (as on 31.3.2000) 11.1 Total Railway Length km. 311 5396 11.2 Total Road Length km. 8695 213951 12. Local Self Government (as on 31.3.1999) 12.1 Village Panchayats No. 1374 27627 12.2 Municipalities (including Corp.) No. 13 239 Source : District Statistical Abstract : Pune District, 1999-2000, Government of Maharashtra 24