Employment and Economic Transformation in Central Asia
Transcription
Employment and Economic Transformation in Central Asia
WEP 2^3/WP.65 WORLD EMPLOYMENT PROGRAMME RESEARCH Labour Market Policies and Programmes Working Paper No. 65 — -I I ... < M . RECEIVED 2 5 MAR 133* International Labour Office ILO BJBL BIT Employment and Economic Transformation in Central Asia Per Ronnas and Orjan Sjoberg Note: WEP Research Working Papers are preliminary documents circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. December 1993 International Labour Office Geneva Copyright © International Labour Organization 1994 Publications of the International Labour Office enjoy copyright under Protocol 2 of the Universal Copyright Convention. Nevertheless, short excerpts from them may be reproduced without authorization, on condition that the source is indicated. For rights of reproduction or translation, application should be made to the Publications Branch (Rights and Permissions), International Labour Office, CH-1211 Geneva 22, Switzerland. The International Labour Office welcomes such applications. ISBN 92-2-109222-4 First published 1994 The designations employed in ILO publications, which are in conformity with United Nations practice, and the presentation of material therein do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the International Labour Office concerning the legal status of any country, area or territory or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers. The responsibility for opinions expressed in signed articles, studies and other contributions rests solely with their authors, and publication does not constitute an endorsement by the International Labour Office of the opinions expressed in them. Reference to names of firms and commercial products and processes does not imply their endorsement by the International Labour Office, and any failure to mention a particular firm, commercial product or process is not a sign of disapproval. ILO publications can be obtained through major booksellers or ILO local offices in many countries, or direct from ILO Publications, International Labour Office, CH-1211 Geneva 22, Switzerland. A catalogue or list of new publications will be sent free of charge from the above address. Printed by the International Labour Office. Geneva, Switzerland PREFACE The newly independent Central Asian republics are in many ways today in a more precarious situation than the countries in East Central Europe were after the revolutions in 1989. They face the dual challenge of transformation from centrally planned economies to market economies and from integrated parts of a larger economy to economic sovereignty. Young and rapidly growing labour forces combined with a high population pressure on land render special importance to the employment aspects of the overall transformation process. The present study was prepared as an input to the increasing involvement of the International Labour Organization in technical assistance to the Central Asian republics and, more specifically, as a background paper for a Conference of Labour Ministers organized by the Turkish Government with technical assistance from the ILO in Ankara, 30-31 May, 1993. A volume on the emerging labour markets in Central Asia, based on this conference, is due for publication in the first half of 1993. The Conference in Ankara has been a basis for further cooperation between the ILO and its constituents in the Central Asian republics. Several areas of active labour market policies are being pursued, including labour relations, labour market information, employment services, training, social safety net provisions and labour standards. The objective is to create labour markets and to make these markets function not only efficiently and equitably, but also have them contribute to economic growth and social justice. This working paper provides an analysis of the employment issues in the Central Asian republics during the transition to a market economy. It takes into account the experience of countries in East Central Europe as well as the specific conditions found in the labour market in Central Asia. It reviews the policy options and provides a framework for further labour market analysis. It also indicates priority areas for active labour market policies and programmes. It is being distributed in its present form because the ILO believes that its results and implications will be of interest to a wider audience (including labour economists, policy makers, and researchers) than attended the Conference in Ankara. Additional copies of this Working Paper may be obtained from Active Labour Market Policies Branch Employment and Development Department International Labour Office 4, route des Morillons CH+1211 Geneva 22 Questions about, comments on, and/or criticisms of this Working Paper are invited. They may be sent to the authors at the above address. December 1993 William Clatanoff Chief, Active Labour Market Policies Branch TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction 1 The transition from central planning to the market: The record 3 The specifics of Central Asia 15 De-linking the externally planned economy 15 Demographic structure 21 Structural characteristics of the Central Asian economies 29 Conclusion: Limited room for manoeuvre 39 A policy agenda 42 I. Introduction Under the system of central planning employment was largely divorced from economic performance. At the enterprise level soft budget constraints ensured that the link was virtually non-existent as labour was allocated to enterprises according to the priority given the type of production pursued rather than efficiency and economic performance. With budget constraints for capital investments - especially in non-priority sectors - usually being somewhat harder, many enterprises also found it expedient to substitute labour for capital. Thus, for individual enterprises labour was a scarce resource to be hoarded and accumulated in as large numbers as possible to permit future growth. The same mode of thinking prevailed at the macro level. The inefficient economy had a seemingly insatiable demand for labour as well as for capital and other resource. Labour was primarily perceived as a scarce resource imposing constraints on a strategy for economic growth which, despite rhetoric to the contrary, by and large depended on mobilising more inputs to produce more outputs. With the shift to a market economy the rules of the game change fundamentally as employment becomes directly linked to economic performance at the enterprise level and, by implication, at the aggregate national level. Experiences from East Central Europe indicate clearly that it takes a long time before the full implications of this fundamental change in the rules of the game dawn upon policy-makers and planners in the countries concerned as well as on overseas expertise called in to provide advice and guidance. The newly independent states in Central Asia1 are in many ways today in a more precarious situation than the countries in East Central Europe were after the revolutions in 1989. Driven to independence by the force of circumstances rather than through own initiative they are ill-prepared to face the dual challenge of transformation from centrally planned economies to market economies and from integrated parts of a larger economy to economic sovereignty. Young and rapidly growing labour forces combined with a high population pressure on land and a 1 Central Asia is here understood to comprise Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, Turkemenistan and Uzbekistan (although in Soviet/CIS usage only the latter four are normally considered to constitute Central Asia proper). 2 generally precarious state of agriculture render crucial importance to the employment aspects of the overall economic transformation processes. For policy-makers steeped in the traditions of central planning this presents a major challenge. They have the potential advantage of being able to draw on the considerable experience and knowledge accumulated on the problems of transformation from centrally planned to market economies in other countries over the past few years, but they can ill afford to repeat the mistakes made elsewhere. The present study examines the demographic, economic and labour market issues facing the Central Asian countries today in the light of the existing knowledge on the functioning of centrally planned economies (Section II). The characteristics and problems of the transformation to market economies in Central Asia are outlined in Section III, with a view to identify the main employment issues and outline the rudiments of a policy agenda for the future (Section IV). 3 II. The transition from central planning to the market: The record The newly independent states in Central Asia face a twofold transition - from centrally planned to market economies and from regions integrated in a larger country to independent states - which will inevitably result in fundamental changes in the economic and social structure of these countries. It is yet much too early and there are far too many uncertain factors involved for predictions on the precise nature of these changes. However, sufficient knowledge has now been accumulated from the experiences of the economies in East Central Europe and elsewhere, notably China and Vietnam, for drawing some general conclusions which, when combined with more specific information about the characteristics of the Central Asian countries, provide a reasonable basis for identification of the main issues and problems ahead. Among the salient features of the transition process the following deserve to be noted as having particular relevance for employment and income generation and policy-making in this field.2 For a number of reasons, the transition inevitably results in a weakening of the state. Firstly, the transition invariably erodes the state finances. This is because old sources of incomes, primarily enterprise profits and implicit sales taxes in the centrally determined price system, decrease abruptly before new sources of revenues are opened up through the development of a tax system more adapted to a market economy.3 Secondly, the administrative capacity and capability of the state machinery is weakened by the shift from direct central planning to indicative planning and the use of new and unfamiliar tools for policy making and policy implementation in an overall environment over which the state has largely lost control 2 This is not the place for any exhaustive analysis of the characteristics of neither central planning nor the transition process. This has been done elsewhere, see for example Janos Kornai, The Socialist System: The political economy of communism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1992), and Anders Aslund, Post<ommunist Economic Revolutions: How big a bang? (Washington, DC: Center for Strategic and International Studies, 1992), respectively. 3 One of the reasons for the relative success of the efforts of fellow Soviet successor state Estonia to move to financial and monetary stability has been its ability to simultaneously 'nationalise' and 'modernise' its system of taxation, processes that were in fact well under way prior to the achievement of full independence; see Ardo H. Hansson, Tranforming an Economy while Building a Nation: The case of Estonia (Working paper, 62. Stockholm: Stockholm Institute of East European Economics, 1992), p. 6. 4 and can no longer expect direct and predictable responses to policy measures. This problem has an important organisational aspect. The previous system was strictly hierarchical and top-heavy, organised along sectoral lines with a virtual absence of horizontal links, particularly at the lower levels of the hierarchy. The result was a situation which can perhaps best be described as sectoral autarky. Another consequence of the top-heavy system was limited room for manoeuvre and decision making at the lower/regional/municipal levels and an accompanying limited capability and competence for independent action. Thirdly, there is a severe lack of reliable information and statistics. The problem is partly inherited from the past when a policy of secrecy prevented the development of information channels and there often were strong incentives to give misleading information and distort statistics. The transition to a more market oriented economy calls for the development of an entirely new system for collection of statistical information and also, often, for new types of statistics. Meanwhile, policy makers and planners lack the information base at a time when it is more needed than ever. Lastly, the collapse of the socialist ideology and the accompanying centrally planned economic system has inevitably had a demoralising effect on the cadres staffing the bureaucracy. There is an obvious danger that a feeling of despondency and impotence may come to prevail at a time when the demands on the state for flexibility and innovativeness have become much greater than in the past. In the case of the newly independent states in Central Asia the previously subservient status and lack of a full-fledged and sovereign state apparatus can only compound the weaknesses of the state. A main conclusion must be that institution building and enhancing the institutional capacity for policy formulation and implementation must be accorded importance in technical assistance. Active labour market policies are only developed gradually and after some delay. This has been a salient feature in all transition economies, with the possible exception of China and Vietnam where concern about poverty alleviation was a contributing factor to the reform process as such. The often slow response to the emerging employment problems can readily be explained as a consequence of the onslaught of a wide range of more acute problems and the limited capability, of the state to tackle these problems. 5 However, there are also more fundamental explanations. Under the previous regime, development objectives were typically stated in terms of physical output, while labour was seen as a scarce resource and a constraint to the attainment of the production targets. In sharp contrast to the situation in most developed and developing market economies, full, though inefficient, utilisation of the labour force was more or less taken for granted and there is no tradition of focusing development planning on the objective of employment and income generation. Even in a country like Hungary, which has been comparatively exposed to the market economies in Western Europe, the preparedness to effectively deal with the emerging employment problems has been little.4 Furthermore, the experience from the transition economies in East Central Europe reveal a considerable time lag before the disruption of the economic system and decline in output is reflected in falling levels of employment. Growth of unemployment has generally been slower than might have been expected,5 thus luring policy-makers and planners into a false sense of lack of urgency. Romania provides a telling example in this respect. Despite a fall of GNP by 20 per cent and of industrial production by 40 per cent in 1990 and 1991, open unemployment was still no more than 3 per cent, though increasing by the end of 1991.6 A main reason behind the delayed effect on employment of economic decline is that continued soft budget constraints and lack of effective competition have made it possible for enterprises to retain surplus labour. Work sharing, reduced work hours and temporary layoffs are often resorted to in order to avoid outright dismissals. In some instances there are also reasons to expect faulty statistics. While the delayed employment effects of economic restructuring and decline may buy policy-makers valuable time, there is a severe risk that it results in an unwarranted sense of relief that the problem of unemployment will prove to be less than initially anticipated. This is clearly an illusion as the lag in the employment response to the 4 Economic Transformation and Employment i/i Hungary (Geneva: ILO, 1992). 5 Tito Boeri and Mark Keese, 'From labour shortage to labour shedding: Labour markets in Central and Eastern Europe', Communist Economies and Economic Transformation, Vol. 4, no. 3 (1992), pp. 373-394, esp. 384. 6 Buletin statistic de informare publico, 1991:12 and 1992:1; Romania Libera, 29 January 1992. By November 1992 the unemployment rate had increased to 9.1 per cent {Buletin statistic de informare publico, 1992:11). 6 changing economic conditions does not imply that employment effects will somehow be avoided, but merely that the bottom has not yet been reached and that there is still a long way to go before the full effects are felt. When the governments react to the emerging employment problems it has initially been in the form of passive labour market policies, such as schemes for unemployment benefits and other types of protection against loss of income.7 This is obviously the easiest type of response, and as such may be explained by the lack of tradition and experience in the field of employment and labour market policies, but it is inadequate and likely to rapidly become unsustainable for cost reasons. Privatisation has proved to be a protracted and technically difficult process. A number of technical solutions have been tried with varying degrees of success and the late starters have today a considerable body of knowledge to draw upon.8 Privatisation has often been portrayed as a key aspect of the economic transition. However, although divestiture of state enterprises and other assets is important as it ensures the institutional separation of the economy from the polity, privatisation is no guarantee for resolving the economic woes associated with the centrally planned economic system. It is useful to make a distinction between privatisation of enterprises on the one hand and marketisation and commercialisation on the other. From the point of view of transition to a market economy, what matters is the enforcement of unambiguous property rights (e.g., throught privatisation) and the subjecting of enterprises to the competitive pressures of markets (i.e., marketisation). This implies basically a rupture of both the vertical links between state enterprises and their superior ministries and horizontal links between the enterprises and local authorities. Enterprises must be given complete responsibility for the management of their own affairs including, most importantly, responsibility for the economic results of its activities. Subsidies and reliance on the state as a lender of last resort in case of financial difficulties must be brought to a definite and unambiguous end in 7 8 OECD Employment Outlook, July 1992 (Paris: OECD, 1992), pp. 258-263. For a review of individual country experiences, see, e.g., Irena Grosfeld and Paul Hare, 'Privatization in Hungary, Poland and Czechoslovakia', European Economy, Special Edition No. 2 (1991), pp. 129-156; Morris Bornstein, 'Privatisation in Eastern Europe', Communist Economies and Economic Transformation, Vol. 4, no. 3 (1992), pp. 283-320; and E.S. Savas, 'Privatization in post-socialist countries', Public Administration Review, Vol. 52, no. 6 (1992), pp. 573-581. 7 order to impose hard budget constraints on the enterprises and complete accountability through commercialisation of their operations. While the necessity of marketisation of enterprises is universally recognised, it has proved difficult to implement in practice. A major problem is the limited number of enterprises, lack of alternative suppliers and buyers and the ensuing dependence of enterprises on each other. To illuminate this problem the economy of the former Soviet Union has been likened to an assembly line.9 Just as closure of one work station along the assembly line will affect all other work stations, bankruptcy of one enterprise will disrupt production in many other enterprises. The result is accumulation of inter-enterprise debts and continued soft budget constraints. Another problem is 'technological pluralism',10 or the considerable technological diversity usually to be found in manufacturing plants in the formerly centrally planned economies. Under the previous economic system new technologies were added to, but did not replace, old ones. As a consequence technologies vary widely both within and between enterprises, as do efficiency, labour productivity and product quality. Under such circumstances imposition of hard budget constraints may in many instances be tantamount to a death warrant. Additionally, acute financial difficulties is not necessarily an indication of lack of long term viability and closure of enterprises in the wake of imposition of hard budget constraints may therefore result in unnecessary waste of productive capacities. The lack of efficient markets lends further support to this argument. In the absence of an independent and competent system for credit appraisal judgements must necessarily remain arbitrary. Lastly, social considerations are an important deterrent to the commercialisation and marketisation of enterprises as large scale redundancies and unemployment inevitably follows in its trail. Most enterprises suffer from considerable overstaffing and even if bankruptcies are averted, the need to increase cost efficiency will in most instances necessitate reductions in the labour force. Slow commercialisation and marketisation of enterprises is the main reason for the relatively modest 9 Axel Leijonhufvud, 'Problems of socialist transformation: Kazakhstan 1991', paper presented at the Arne Ryde Symposium 'Transition Problems' at Rungsted Kyst, Denmark, 11-12 June 1992. 10 Alin Teodorescu, The future of a failure: the Romanian economy', in Orjan Sjdberg and Michael L. Wyzan (eds.), Economic Change in the Balkan States: Albania, Bulgaria, Romania and Yugoslavia (London: Pinter, 1991), pp. 69-82, at p. 75. 8 unemployment effects of the economic contraction. However, while it provides a respite, it does not offer any long term solution. Another universal experience is that markets take a long time to develop, in particular in countries that are shielded from the effects of foreign trade. In the absence of competition the price elasticity of the supply of many goods remains low. Lack of alternative suppliers and poor information channels easily result in monopolistic abuses in the wake of price liberalisations. A related problem is the difficulty to assess production costs in a situation of extreme technological plurality. While capital and labour markets often emerge early, often at the very instant the old economic system gives way, they take a particularly long time to develop into fulfledged markets. Neither can be expected to develop spontaneously, except in a highly rudimentary form, and as both are instrumental to economic growth and employment and income generation active government policies in these fields are required. The need for fundamental economic restructuring has, if anything, proved to be even greater than previously expected. The past development strategy and economic system created highly dysfunctional economic structures. While the individual countries display different needs of economic restructuring, these differences are largely variations around the same theme and it is quite possible to make a number of generalisations. Firstly, all the former socialist countries have a bias towards heavy industry in their economic structure as a result of the emphasis under the previous development strategy on producer goods industry as a spearhead of economic development and modernisation. Thus, they are left with a bloated heavy industry which, as a result of the priority in terms of allocation of production factors that it enjoyed in the past, typically also suffers from particularly pronounced overstaffing. The emphasis on physical production and the division of the economy into a productive and a non-productive sphere during the socialist period resulted in an underdevelopment of most services. Generally speaking, the share of the labour force in the industry is ten to twenty percentage units higher than in market economies at corresponding levels of development.11 Under the past economic system these sectoral priorities were also reflected in 11 OECD Employment Outlook, July 1991 (Paris: OECD, 1991), pp. 17-19. 9 the wage structure. Beyond the general practice of 'determination of wages from the residual left by accumulation',12 tariff rates, based on skill classification and production norms, tended to be biased in favour of not only the 'productive sphere' (as opposed to the non-productive sectors, including services), but also in favour of the heavy end of manufacturing. As a consequence the supply of many services is not only under-dimensioned, but also of poor quality. Although this state of affairs would seem to reflect the existence of a rather substantial wage spread, it was partly off-set by two countervailing tendencies. Firstly, for egalitarian and other ideological reasons, attempts were made to keep money wages within a rather narrow range (both wage drift and non-wage benefits, however, worked to the advantage of those in priority sectors). Secondly, reclassification of skill grades were often made, so as to enable employers to pay higher wages should labour supply at the official rate fall short of actual demand. In turn, the discretionary nature of such measures conspired with the importance of non-wage benefits and the narrow range of cash remuneration to reduce labour mobility. By and large it is fair to say that the wage structure displayed considerable rigidities and that in the absence of any genuine mechanisms for wage bargaining the links between demand and supply of labour on the one hand and the wage structure on the other hand were poorly developed. Remnants of these rigidities remain an important obstacle to smoothly functioning labour markets. The former socialist countries also display an exaggerated bias towards large scale enterprises and a severe lack of small and medium sized economic units.13 The emphasis on large scale enterprises was ostensibly due to a belief in economies of scale, but is more likely to have been conditioned by the limited capacity at the central level to monitor and plan a large number of units. For different, system determined reasons the degree of specialisation at the enterprise level is very low. Most enterprises produce a large variety of goods and services that are often seemingly unrelated to their main line of production. Under the centrally planned economic system, such diversification made good sense as a means of achieving internal flexibility and lessening the dependence on highly arbitrary supplies of out12 Silvana Malle, Employment Planning in the Soviet Union (Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1990), p. 228. 13 OECD Employment Outlook, July 1991, p. 19. 10 side services and goods. However, as the economies shift towards a market economy, the lack of internal specialisation within enterprises becomes a handicap. More often than not the production of the subsidiary or supplementary goods and services is costly and inefficient. It detracts resources from the main line of production, prevents economies of scale and is likely to have an overall negative effect on the viability of the enterprises. A complicating factor in this regard is that the degree of mechanisation tends to be much higher in the main line of production than in the auxiliary and ancillary activities. Comprehensive restructuring of the economies will have obvious and farreaching effects on employment. Restructuring results, within a relatively short period of time, in severe mismatches in the supply and demand structure of labour which puts unreasonable strain on the nascent labour markets. Increases in the overall unemployment are paralleled by severe shortages of critical skills, which appear already at an early stage of the transition. To give but one example, there is typically a surplus of engineers and several other related professional skills, while there is be a shortage of competence in almost all fields of economics and business administration and in the legal professions. To make matters worse, labour mobility - both occupational and geographical - tends to be low. The reasons are severalfold. Some are related to an inappropriate structure of incentives and may fairly easily be remedied, although the deterring impact of a poor supply of food products in urban areas on rural-urban migration may prove less easy to redress. More fundamental reasons behind low geographical mobility include the existence of administrative restrictions facing those wanting to change domicile, the lack of a housing market and the continued importance of an extensive network of informal contacts, while a main reason behind the low occupational mobility is the narrow educational profile of much of the labour force as a consequence of past policies of favouring skill related over general education. The bias towards large scale enterprises has left most regions and towns with an extremely narrow and lopsided economic base. In fact, many towns are best characterised as 'company towns' as their economy rests on (and falls with) one or two large enterprises. In most of the Central Asian countries this problem is aggravated by a poorly developed urban network and poor economic and physical infrastructure 11 outside the main city, or cities. The previous reliance on vertical chains of command imply that horizontal contacts and linkages, vital to regional economic revival, need to be developed from scratch. The regional aspects of the economic restructuring and transition must therefore be given close attention, as the closure of individual enterprises may have devastating effects on local economies and non-farm employment opportunities. This is particularly important, as democratization and decentralization of decision making have given local authorities a totally new and much more powerful mandate. However, the local administrative apparatuses, which in the past were mere extended arms of the central authorities, are illequipped to tackle the daunting regional development problems. In the wake of the sweeping economic reforms, most of the formerly socialist countries have seen a rapid increase in small scale entrepreneurship. Because of the more lenient attitudes of their respective governments during the years leading up to 1989, Poland and Hungary had a head start in this respect, and the etablishment and expansion of private businesses quickly got under way there.14 But even where prospective entrepreneurs were not encouraged in this manner the private sector is flourishing and small scale enterprises are mushrooming. Thus, two years after the revolution Romania boasted over 300,000 new private enterprises and an Albanian organisation for entrepreneurs claims a membership of over ZO.OOO.15 While this is obviously very encouraging for a variety of reasons, not least that of employment and income generation, it should be seen as an opportunity for active policy making and assistance rather than as an excuse for complacency. The process of 'privatisation from below* is impressive in terms of numbers of enterprises rather than in terms of production or employment. The vast majority of the new enterprises are extremely small and tend to suffer from a lack of capital, knowhow, supply sources and market outlets. They are heavily concentrated to certain types of services, while the establishment of new enterprises in the manufacturing sector has been slow. The scant statistical data available also indicate high turnover rates. The small scale of the enterprises implies that they generate primarily self14 Simon Johnson, 'Private business in Eastern Europe', paper prepared for the 'NBER conference on the Economic Transformation of Eastern Europe', Cambridge, MA, 26-29 February 1992. 15 Buletin statistic de informare publico, 1991:12, and Qirjako Noti, personal communication, 18 April 1992, respectively. 12 employment and very little wage employment. As such they do not provide a ready solution for absorbing the increasing ranks of unemployed. There is nothing to suggest that unemployed industrial workers are particularly suited for self-employment and as entrepreneurs. Indeed, a recent study of Hungary16 revealed that only 8 per cent of the new entrepreneurs had a background as previously unemployed. On the contrary, empirical evidence from other countries suggests that rather specific skills and personal characteristics are required to become a successful entrepreneur, quite apart from the fact that it requires access to capital, inputs, markets and so forth.17 Hence, the main challenge and potential lies in fostering the growth of the new enterprises rather than in their multiplication. Only through growth will they be able to assume an important role as instruments for employment and income generation and make a contribution towards rectifying the lopsided and unbalanced economic structure. Thus, favourable conditions for growth of small enterprises need to be created. The Central Asian countries may here benefit from the experiences of other countries in transition, not least China and Vietnam, but also Poland and Hungary. A conducive political climate and institutional setting, including an adequate framework of economic legislation and efficient law enforcement, and efficient markets for capital and labour are essential conditions.18 Experience from China strongly suggest that fostering of linkages between the nascent small scale sector and the established large scale enterprises may be a key factor,19 as has also been observed with respect to, for instance, Czechoslovakia.20 This would seem to be of particular relevance to the Central Asian countries where the incipient disturbance of trade with the rest of the former Soviet Union has created an urgent 16 Economic Transformation, p. 33. 17 Per Ronnas, Employment Generation through Private Entrepreneurship in Vietnam (New Delhi: ILO-ARTEP/SIDA, 1992). 18 Ronnas, Employment Generation. 19 Per Ronnas and Orjan Sjdberg, Township enterprises: A part of the world or a world apart?', paper prepared for the '3rd European Conference on Agricultural and Rural Development in China', 15-18 April 1993, SchloB Rauischholzhausen, GieBen, Germany. 20 Gerald A. McDermott and Michal Mejstrik, "The role of small firms in the industrial development and transformation of Czechoslovakia', Small Business Economics, Vol. 4, no. 3 (1992), pp. 179200. 13 need for new backward and forward linkages for existing enterprises. Provision of physical premises, technical assistance and extension services would also seem to be highly needed.21 The severe dislocation of trade and economic contacts resulting from the breakdown of the Soviet Union must also be taken into consideration. For the countries in East Central Europe and Vietnam the effects were felt with full force in 1991. Two main conclusions may be drawn from their experiences. Firstly, that the effect on the domestic economies are likely to be both abrupt and devastating. Thus, the sharp decline in industrial production in Romania in the second half of 1991 by some 22 per cent can largely be attributed to an acute energy shortage following a disruption of deliveries from the Soviet Union.22 Similar effects were, to a varying degree, registered in the other countries. Secondly, the recovery of the domestic economies and compensation of trade losses through reorientation of trade has in several of the countries been surprisingly rapid. This is particularly the case in Vietnam, where a complete reorientation of trade patterns has been achieved in a very short period of time and the dislocative effects on the economy would seem to have been overcome after only a year. Though less dramatic, the adaptation of the countries in East Central Europe also provide reason for cautious optimism. However, there is nothing automatic about the recovery and any terms-of-trade losses from a shift to world market prices are likely to become permanent. The disruption of trade may both act as a catalyst to reform, by speeding up reform measures and forcing enterprises out into the cold, and make it more difficult. In particular, it makes it difficult to impose hard budget constraints on enterprises as enterprises with sound long term development perspective may face acute difficulties due to temporary shortages of energy or inputs or loss of markets. Lastly, it may be noted that countries that have opted for swift comprehensive reforms and adjustment have been relatively more successful than those which have taken a more gradual and partial approach.23 The contrasting cases of Vietnam and 21 Ronnas, Employment Generation. 22 Social and Economic Standing of Romania in the Year 1991 (Bucharest: National Commission for Statistics, 1992), pp. 6-7. 23 E.g., Aslund, Post-communist Economic Revolutions. 14 Poland on the one hand and Russia and Romania on the other are persuasive illustrations of this. The strategy adopted by Vietnam would seem to be of particular interest, as the transition in Vietnam has been both swift and highly successful and has confuted odds which initially seemed rather poor. However, in reality the choice is obviously not so straight forward. The discussion above provides ample illustration of the difficulties of achieving a rapid transition at the same time as external factors and the force of circumstances may necessitate improvisations implies a risk that strategies become reactive rather than proactive. 15 III. The specifics of Central Asia a) De-linking the externally planned economy The institutional and economic setting in Central Asia displays many inherited features familiar from the above outline of East Central Europe and former constituent republics of the now defunct Soviet Union. To a considerable extent Central Asia also shares with them the agenda for change, now that central planning has been given up. It is nevertheless important to recognise the existence of dissimilar features, some of them singular to the Central Asian states. These unique features do not detract from the argument that the state finds itself weakened because of the political and economic processes unleashed by the collapse of Soviet hegemony and central planning. Rather, the case can be made that these peculiarities weaken the state further still, thereby eroding its capacity for making positive contributions to reform. Firstly, as Martha Brill Olcott has observed, '[f]ew peoples of the world have ever been forced to become independent nations. Yet this is precisely what happened to the five Central Asian republics after Russia, Belarus and Ukraine - the three original signatories of the USSR's founding 1922 constitution - met in Minsk on December 8, 1991, and created a new Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS).'24 The Central Asian republics thus faced the choice of full independence or becoming members of the new Commonwealth and as 'Central Asia's leaders knew that the mere act of declaring independence would resolve few of their economic or political problems',25 the latter alternative appeared to have considerable merit. Secondly, although difficult in practice, it is useful to distinguish between the effects of economic transformation and nation building.26 With no recent history of independence, Central Asian states are in a quite different position as compared to those former republics of the Soviet Union that have the cause of re-establishing their sovereignty to rally around, the difference being larger still as compared to the 24 Martha Brill Olcott, 'Central Asia's catapult to independence', Foreign Affairs, Vol. 71, no. 3 (1992/93), pp. 108-130, quotation from p. 108. 25 Ibid., p. 114. 26 As convincingly argued by Hansson, Transforming an Economy, p. 13. 16 countries of East Central Europe which never had to give up their formal independence in the first place. While the latter group of countries can, by and large, focus their attention and efforts on economic reform, Central Asian states have also to consider the demands of nation building. These demands may, but need not, require similar sets of policy action. Thirdly, being an integral part of a larger political entity, Central Asia has been strongly influenced by that entity. In particular, two characteristics which follow from the fact that Central Asia was integrated into the centrally planned economy of the Soviet Union deserve to be singled out. Firstly, central planning authority vested with the all-union Gosplan effectively removed a sizeable portion of economic activities in the region from the control of republican and local authorities in Central Asia. Secondly, and as a corollary, central planning made it possible to impose on Central Asia a measure of regional specialisation without therefore necessarily taking comparative advantage into account.27 Combined these two strands worked to turn the Central Asian republics into suppliers of raw materials (fossil fuels, minerals and cash crops), with little domestic processing, premature resource depletion and environmental degradation as major consequences. In particular, in agriculture regional specialisation implied a substitution of cash crop mono-culture (cotton) for diversification and food production, thereby increasing the dependence on food imports. It has been argued that the above described situation amounted to no less than an outright colonial pattern,28 and that the Central Asian states are now entering a 27 Basing himself on oblast level per capita investment data for the period 1956-1985, Ronald D. Liebowitz, 'Soviet geographical imbalances and Soviet Central Asia', in Robert Lewis (ed.), Geographic Perspectives on Soviet Central Asia (London: Routledge, 1992), pp. 101-131, at p. 116, concludes that 'it appears as if Soviet investment practice has been geared more toward developing the economic capacity of Central Asia to meet the needs of the national economy than with developing and equalizing the productive capacities and socioeconomic conditions of the southern tier.' 28 E.g., Martin C. Spechler, 'Regional development in the USSR, 1958-78', in Soviet Economy in a Time of Change: A compendium ofpapers submitted to the Joint Economic Committee of the Congress of the United States, Vol. 1 (Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office, 1979), pp. 141-163, labelling the phenomenon 'welfare colonialism' (p. 145); Michael Rywkin, Moscow's Muslim Challenge: Soviet Central Asia (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1990, rev. ed.), speaking of, for instance, 'colonial conquest' (p. 18) and approvingly quoting Spechler (p. 56); Leslie Dienes, Soviet Asia: Economic development and national policy choices (Boulder, CO: Westview, 1987), p. 6, who contends that Central Asia is a "plantation economy" in its relationship to the metropolis [i.e., Moscow]'; and Liebowitz, 'Soviet 17 phase of 'decolonialisation'. While suggestive, this characterisation conceals a number of peculiarities, such as the role of transfers from the all-union budget. Above all, and despite the removal of direct control from a geographically distant centre, it conceals the fact that the transition from central planning to a market economy, a process which runs in parallel to the de-linking of the 'externally planned' economy, erodes the capacity of the state to act autonomously. Central Asia and the other former republics of the Soviet Union are in a more precarious position than the former centrally planned economies of East Central and South Eastern Europe, as the latter have entered the process of economic transition with full-fledged (though often inadequate) state administrations in place.29 Taken as a whole, the above features constitute an important backdrop to the transition as such and are therefore worth looking into in greater detail. The high degree of integration of the Central Asian countries with the rest of the former Soviet Union and their extreme trade dependence on Russia and the other CIS member states (see Table 1) renders paramount importance to the issue of dislocation of trade and economic contacts. The potentially extremely serious effects of trade dislocations are further underscored by the poorly diversified vertical linkages and the high dependence of enterprises on a small number of suppliers and buyers. To pursue the parallel with the assembly line, it is as though the line would be cut off between the various work stations. Although it is beyond the scope of the present study to examine in depth the consequences of the dislocation of trade within the former Soviet Union, it is clearly a factor of utmost importance to the development of the economies in Central Asia. It must therefore be a major consideration in policy making. At first glance the more pronounced integration into, and hence dependence on, the all-union economy and the limited capacity to compensate for any negative effects of such a disruption of trade would seem to put Central Asia in a much worse position than the non-Soviet members of the defunct Comecon were. geographical imbalances', pp. 119-122, who adopts the term 'internal colonialism' originally coined by Michael Hechter, Internal Colonialism: The Celtic Fringe in British national development (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1975). 29 For useful distinctions in this regard, see Hansson, Transforming an Economy. 18 A closer examination of the effects of the adjustment of the terms of trade of individual CIS member states shows a rather mixed pattern. Preliminary calculations made by the World Bank suggests that energy exporters among the republics of the former Soviet Union stand to gain from the introduction of world market prices; in Central Asia, this includes Turkmenistan and Kazakhstan.30 Exporters of other raw materials such as precious metals and minerals may also be expected to gain, although to a lesser extent. This is not a zero sum game, however, and as the former Soviet Union as a whole is expected to improve its standing through the shift to world prices, chances are that also republics relatively poorly endowed with natural resources may stand to gain as the transition is accomplished.31 Furthermore, republics running deficits in their trade with other republics (such as Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan and Uzbekistan), may find that the loss of inter-republic transfers is more of a shock to their economies than the adjustment of their terms of trade. Nevertheless, in countries dependent on imports of fossil fuels, the impact of these changes will most severely be felt in energy intensive industries, and governments may therefore find a need to identify means whereby the impact can be reduced in the short term. In the medium and long term, however, there is no viable option but to realign the operations of those enterprises severly hit by the adjustment in the terms of trade. 30 David G. Tarr, How Moving to World Prices Affects the Terms of Trade in 15 Countries of the Former Soviet Union. (Policy Research Working Papers, WPS 1074. Washington, DC: Country Economics Department, The World Bank, 1993). 31 However, as Tarr is careful to point out, during the transition itself a very different set of prices may prevail. As a consequence, despite a favourable long term outlook, the immediate impact may well be much to the detriment of individual states or industries. 19 Table 1 Share of inter-republican trade in total trade, 1988 Total export, mil. rubles X within USSR X outside USSR Total import, mil. rubles X within USSR X outside USSR Exports as X of imports, total within USSR outside USSR Source: Turkmenistan Uzbekistan Azerbaijan Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan Tajikistan 6,800 94.1 9,100 91.2 2,560 97.7 2,600 92.3 5.9 8.8 2.3 2,330 85.8 14.2 7.7 10,490 85.4 14.6 5.700 75.4 24.6 16,400 83.5 16.5 3,770 79.6 20.4 3,490 86.5 13.5 2,900 86.2 13.8 12,320 86.2 13.8 68 83 8 67 66 70 90 96 50 85 84 90 119 149 29 55 61 30 Murat Albegov, 'Problems of regional development in the USSR under perestroika', in Tibor Vasko (ed.), Problems of Economic Transition (Aldershot: Avebury, 1992), p. 149. However, this worst case scenario has not yet materialised. Two circumstances appear to explain why this is the case. Firstly, the reorientation has not been as swift as was the case with intra-Comecon trade. Indeed, Central Asian leaders have been careful not to immediately severe economic ties with the fellow members of the CIS, the reason being the acute awareness of Cental Asian economic vulnerability.32 Secondly, the trade pattern between Russia and Central Asia is dissimilar to the intraComecon trade in as much as it is not one of Russia exporting unprocessed raw materials, and receiving manufactured goods in return. Russian-Central Asian trade comprises flows of raw materials from Central Asia and with manufactured goods being exported from the centre. This might in the past have reduced any positive impact of receiving subsidised Russian fuels and ores, but makes local industry less exposed today. Furthermore, it implies that gains are to be made, should the Central Asian republics find buyers willing to pay world market prices rather than the low Olcott, 'Central Asia's catapult', pp. 115-118. 20 procurement prices obtained in intra-Soviet trade. The fact that the policy of regional specialisation pursued in the former Soviet Union has left the Central Asian countries extremely trade dependent and with lopsided economic structures implies that, irrespective of the political philosophy of the future governments in Central Asia, diversification of the economic structure and increased self-sufficiency will inevitably be a main objective of the economic strategy. Economic diversification and a higher degree of processing of domestic raw materials will also provide the main context and area for future entrepreneurial development and employment and income generation. A tentative conclusion would therefore be that in the long term the de-linking from the economy of the former Soviet Union may well be advantageous from the point of view of employment generation. However, a rapid and uncontrolled disruption of this link would more likely than not wreck havoc on these economies and result in mass unemployment and economic misery. All told, a swift reorientation of trade away from the CIS countries, as witnessed for instance in Estonia and Latvia, seems unlikely. Unlike these Baltic countries, the Central Asian republics are distant from the main world markets and lack natural alternative trading partners, at least in the short run. The geographical layout of existing physical infrastructure will also continue to favour trade relations with CIS members for the foreseeable future. In particular, railways and pipelines are predominatly oriented towards Russia, and it will be some time before alternative routes are opened up. Therefore, a geographical restructuring of trade patterns is likely to be gradual and the Central Asian countries will no doubt remain heavily dependent on trade with Russia and other CIS members for some time. The low level of complementarity between the Central Asian republics (except for fossil fuels) will continue to reduce the scope for intra-regional trade. By implication, economic recovery will be heavily dependent on the fortunes Russia and its economy. The only thing which might distort this picture would be increases in exports of energy and other raw materials. A caveat therefore needs to be introduced for Kazakhstan in particular but also Turkmenistan. 21 Demographical structure b) While the effects of the as yet gradual and partial de-linking of the Central Asian economies from that of the Commonwealth shows a rather mixed picture, demography presents a challenge of a different order. Although the present size of the population of the area - amounting to 57.4 million people, the equivalent of 14 inhabitants/km2 - might not seem alarming (see Table 2), prospects for the future are somewhat more somber than overall numbers and densities suggest. Table 2 Population and population densities, 1989 Azerbaijan Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan Tajikistan Turkmenistan Uzbekistan Total Source: Population Area (km2) 7 16 4 5 3 20 57 86 600 2 717 300 198 500 143 100 488 100 447 400 4 081 000 131 000 691 000 367 000 248 000 662 000 322 000 381 000 Density (inn./km2) 82.3 6.1 22.0 36.7 7.4 45.4 H.I Demograficheskiy ezhegodnik SSSR 1990 (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1990), pp. 11-12. For a start, because of the existence of large tracts of semi-arid or arid land in the region, population densities in inhabitable areas are much higher than the national aggregates imply. In fact, within Central Asia one finds some of the most densely populated provinces within the entire Commonwealth, with those located in the fertile Fergana Valley displaying particularly high figures (e.g., in 1990, Andijan 419.3 inh./km 2 ; Fergana 308.2 inh./km 2 ). The situation is much the same throughout Turkmenistan, Uzbekistan and southern Kazakhstan, where the population has been concentrated to river valleys or other reliable sources of water. Elsewhere, 22 such as in parts of Tajikistan, a forbidding topography serves to concentrate the population geographically. Furthermore, given the rather high ratio of rural to urban dwellers in four of the six states under consideration (Tables 3 and 4), the high densities are often rural rather than urban in origin, with the provinces of the Fergana Valley again registering the highest values (Andijan 283.1 and Fergana 209.4 rural inh./km2). As a consequence, and in spite of the efforts of expanding the arable area through extensive irrigation schemes in particular in Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan, overall population to arable land ratios do not give much comfort in this regard (Table 10 below), only Kazakhstan being an exception. Table 3 Rural/Urban Distribution of the Population in Central Asia (excluding Azerbayan and Kazakhstan) Central Asia no X Kyrgyzstan n o X Tajikistan n o X Urban population 696 33.7 646 32.6 1959 1970 1979 1989 1990 4 7 10 13 13 771 531 362 017 273 34.9 38.0 40.7 39.6 39.6 1 098 1 366 1 641 1 664 37.4 38.7 38.2 38.1 1959 1970 1979 1989 1990 8 12 15 19 20 911 261 118 826 286 65.1 61.9 59.3 60.4 60.4 1 370 1 836 2 163 2 650 2 703 66.3 62.6 61.3 61.8 61.9 1 007 1 325 1 667 1 684 37.1 34.9 32.6 32.2 Turkmenistan n o X n Uzbekistan o X 700 1 034 1 323 1 603 1 638 46.2 47.9 48.0 45.4 45.2 2 4 6 8 8 729 322 348 106 282 33.6 36.6 41.2 40.7 40.8 816 1 125 1 436 1 931 1 984 53.8 52.1 52.0 54.6 54.8 5 7 9 11 12 390 477 043 800 040 66.4 63.4 58.8 59.3 59.2 Rural population Sources: 1 1 2 3 3 335 823 476 445 559 67.4 62.9 65.1 67.4 67.8 Naselenie SSSR1988. Statisticheskiy ezhegodnik (Moscow. Finansy i statistika, 1989), pp. 24-26; Demograficheskiy ezhegodnik SSSR 1990 (Moscow Finansy i statistika, 1990), pp. 11-12. 23 Table 4 Rural/Urban Distribution of the Population in Azerbaijan and Kazakhstan Kazakhstan Azerba ijan no Sources: X no X 1959 1970 1979 1989 1990 1 767 2 564 3 200 3 785 3 840 Urban population 47.8 50.1 53.1 53.8 53.8 4 067 6 538 7 920 9 465 9 586 43.8 50.3 53.9 57.2 57.4 1959 1970 1979 1989 1990 1 931 2 553 2 828 3 244 3 291 Rural population 52.2 49.9 46.9 46.2 46.2 5 226 6 471 6 764 7 073 7 105 56.2 49.7 46.1 42.8 42.5 Naselenie SSSR 1988. Statisticheskiy ezhegodnUc (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1989), pp. 23,26; Demograficheskiy ezhegodnik SSSR 1990 (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1990), pp. 11-12. A second, related and more pressing concern is population growth. Table 6 details natural growth over the ten years spanning the period 1980 to 1989. As these are crude figures, the increase in natural growth over much of the 1980s is attributable to the effects of the age structure of the population. The outstanding message of Table 6, however, is the high level of population growth, in particular in Tajikistan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan, amounting to a doubling of the population in about 25 to 30 years or less. Especially rural growth, while in keeping with world patterns of urban-rural differentials, are high by any standard. In terms of absolute figures, this implies that much of Central Asia can be expected to grow by substantial annual increments in the foreseeable future, irrespective whether any major changes in reproductive behaviour take place or not (and total fertility rates generally do appear to be decreasing).33 The rapid increase in rural numbers have until recently been compounded by the typically low rates of rural out-migration.34 In commenting on the low propensity to 33 Naselenie SSSR 1987. Statisticheskiy ezhegodnik (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1989), pp. 328-343; and Demograficheskiy ezhegodnik SSSR 1990 (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1990), pp. 308-315. 24 leave rural areas, observers have instead noted the significance of 'reverse migration', the main reason for which is to be found in the emphasis on cash crops production and the concomitant expansion of land grown to cotton.35 Others emphasise the possibility of informal sector activities open to rural dwellers and to those engaged in agriculture, which together with a generally superior supply of food stuffs are thought to entice people to stay on the land or indeed to return from urban areas.36 Less frequently commented upon, but clearly of some importance in this regard, has been the system of movement controls imposed on rural dwellers throughtout the former Soviet Union. Amounting to no less than a system of 'territorial administration of privilege',37 rural retention policies have long been in place. Partly as a consequence of the lifting, or collapse, of such policies and partly as a consequence of economic reform rural out-migration can be expected to increasingly become a prominent feature of Central Asian labour markets. Table 5 provides some information on rural-to-urban drift. Although sharp increases were registered in several countries between 1989 and 1990, the overall level of rural outmigration remained low. Except for Kyrgyzstan where out-migration ostensibly reached a staggering 8 per cent in 1990, net out-migration remained below the rate of natural increase with continued increasing rural populations as a result. However, a word of caution must be introduced as the reliability of the migration data is uncertain. Indeed, in several instances it is not fully compatible with other statistics. Furthermore, the general increase in migration in 1990 is perhaps the first sign of a new development which may rapidly gain pace. Clearly, this is an issue which will require very careful monitoring. 34 For information on the state of affairs prior to the lifting of administrative restrictions on rural out-migration, see, e.g., the information contained in Demograficheskiy ezhegodnik SSSR 1990 (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1990), Chapter 7. 35 Gregory Gleason, 'National sentiment and migration in Soviet Central Asia', Nationalities Papers, Vol. XV, no. 2 (1987), pp. 228-244, at p. 232, 36 The most well-known study being Nancy Lubin, Labour and Nationality in Soviet Central Asia (London: Macmillan, 1984). 37 Graham E. Smith, 'Privilege and place in Soviet society', in Derek Gregory and Rex Walford (eds.), Horizons in Human Geography (Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1989), pp. 320-340, esp. 328-33S. Table 5 Rural out-migration, 1979-1990 Azerbaijan Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan Tajikistan Turkmenistan Uzbekistan 1979-1988 annual average 1989 1990 78 142 63 29 11 39 87 800 143 100 56 100 20 900 6 100 59 500 64 100 165 700 133 400 42 300 18 400 62 400 200 800 800 900 200 400 Source: T. Levina, 'Demograficheskaya situatsiya v sel'skoy mestnosti', Vestnik stalistiki, 1992:1, p. 11. Table 6 Natural population growth, 1980-1989 (per 1,000 inhabitants) 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 Azerbaijan urban rural 18.2 16.4 20.2 19.4 17.3 21.9 18.5 16.6 20.8 19.5 17.1 22.1 19.8 17.7 22.0 19.8 17.8 22.3 20.9 18.8 23.3 20.1 18.3 22.3 19.6 17.3 22.3 20.0 16.9 23.5 Kazakhstan urban rural 15.9 14.0 18.1 16.4 14.5 18.6 16.5 14.4 19.2 16.5 14.2 19.3 17.2 14.8 20.3 17.1 14.9 19.9 18.2 15.6 21.7 18.1 15.9 21.1 17.1 14.7 20.3 15.4 12.6 19.3 Kyrgyzstan urban rural 21.2 17.1 21.2 22.7 18.0 25.5 23.4 17.6 26.9 23.5 17.8 26.9 23.7 18.5 26.9 23.9 18.4 27.4 25.6 19.7 29.2 25.4 19.3 29.0 24.0 18.2 27.5 23.2 16.5 27.3 Tajikistan urban rural 28.9 20.5 33.5 30.5 21.8 35.1 30.5 22.0 34.9 30.7 21.8 35.3 32.4 24.2 36.5 33.0 23.6 37.6 35.3 26.0 39.9 35.0 26.3 39.3 33.2 22.7 38.2 32.2 21.9 37.3 Turkmenistan urban rural 26.0 21.5 30.0 25.8 21.2 30.0 26.7 22.9 30.1 26.7 22.0 30.7 27.0 23.2 30.4 27.9 23.6 31.6 28.5 25.1 31.4 29.4 25.5 32.7 28.3 24.8 31.1 27.3 24.3 29.6 Uzbekistan urban rural 26.4 18.3 32.0 27.8 19.7 33.4 27.7 20.3 32.8 27.9 21.1 32.6 28.8 21.9 33.6 30.2 22.7 35.2 30.8 23.0 36.3 30.2 22.9 35.3 28.4 21.2 33.5 27.0 19.5 32.1 Source: Demograficheskiy ezhegodnik SSSR1990 (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1990), pp. 99-106. 26 The sustained high rates of natural increase has resulted in a broad based population pyramid and a large young dependent population, indicating that there will be a rapid increase in the working age population at least over the short and medium term. This impression is indeed brought out by Table 7, which gives the relative shares of working age and below working age population in 1989, respectively. In particular, the rural areas of Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan have a large share of their population below the age of 16, in no case making up less than two-fifths of the total rural population. An assessment of the growth of the working age population over the next ten years as based on the current age structure of the population of the Central Asian states (Table 8) corroborates the suggestion that the size of the labour force will increase at a fast pace.38 Although in most cases diminishing or at least levelling out over time, the annual net addition to those in working age will remain substantial throughout the 1990s, a fact which will put all the Central Asian states under considerable pressure to create new job opportunities lest unemployment rates will skyrocket. The circumstance that these supply side pressures are rural in origin underscores the need to attach importance to the rural and regional aspects of economic development and employment planning, but does little to change the general perception of urgency. 38 Data for 1979-1989 are based on the working age population at the beginning and at the end of the period as given by census returns. The calculations leading to the projections for 1990-1999 are based on a number of assumptions, all of which render data somewhat approximate. Firstly, no migration is assumed to take place. Secondly, mortality is assumed to be proportional over the age groups upon which the calculations are based, an assumption which can be expected to make the estimates conservative as mortality in the 45-54 (women)/50-59 (men) year groups of in the 1989 census (making up the group of people leaving the working age interval over the coming years up 1999) are likely to be higher than among the 6-15 year olds (the new entrants during the same period). 27 Table 7 Relative shares of working age and below working age population, 1989 (in per cent) Working age Below working age Azerbaijan Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan Tajikistan Turkmenistan Uzbekistan Total urban rural Total urban rural 34.6 33.7 39.5 45.1 42.7 42.9 32.5 29.9 32.0 37.8 38.0 36.8 37.2 38.8 44.1 48.6 46.6 47.1 55.4 55.1 50.3 47.3 49.7 49.1 57.3 58.3 56.3 52.9 53.5 53.7 53.0 51.0 46.6 44.6 46.6 45.6 Remark: The residual in each case is equal to the above working age population in the respective countries. Source: Demograficheskiy ezhegodnik SSSR 1990 (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1990), pp. 27-74. Table 8 Net average annual increase in working age population, 1979-1999 (in per cent) Azerbaijan Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan Tajikistan Turkmenistan Uzbekistan Source: 1979-1989 1990-1994 1995-1999 2.2 1.3 2.1 3.6 3.2 3.2 1.8 1.8 2.6 3.3 3.1 3.0 2.0 1.7 2.7 3.5 3.1 3.2 Calculations based on Demograficheskiy ezhegodnik SSSR 1990 (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1990), pp. 27-74. 28 Table 9 Ethnic structure of the population in 1989 (in per cent) Azerbaijan Titular nation Russians Other minorities Sources: 83 6 11 Kazakhstan 40 38 22 Kyrgyzstan 52 22 26 Tajikistan 62 8 30 Turkmenistan Uzbekistan 72 10 18 71 8 21 Roland Gotz and Uwe Halbach, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (III)', Osteuropa, Vol. 42, no. 8 (1992), pp. 680-693; idem, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (IV)', Osteuropa, Vol. 42, no. 10 (1992), pp. 887-907. The above picture is made more complex by the fact that the countries under discussion all have sizeable minorities besides the titular nation (Table 9). Indeed, in the case of Kazakhstan, the Kazakhs make up no more than two-fifths of the total, with the second largest group, the Russians, at 38 per cent of the population, being almost as numerous. The various ethnical groups tend to have differing propensities to migrate and display different patterns of reproductive behaviour as well.39 Partly this reflects the non-proportional allocation of the members of the major ethnical groups between urban and rural areas, but it may nevertheless have implications for future changes in the rate of growth of the working age population. By way of conclusion, high and in some cases intensifying pressures on the supply side will increasingly put the Central Asian labour markets under strain. The severity of the problem of absorption and how the countries in focus will cope with the situation is, however, partly a question of economic structure and performance, issues to which we now turn. 39 See, e.g., Richard H. Rowland, 'Demographic trends in Soviet Central Asia and southern Kazakhstan', in Robert Lewis (ed.), Geographic Perspectives on Soviet Central Asia (London: Routledge, 1992), pp. 222-250. 29 c) Structural characteristics of the Central Asian economies The above description of the demographic structure and likely future trends of population growth gives only a bare outline of the nature and magnitude of the problems laying ahead. For the identifiction of further implications for labour market and employment developments the characteristics of the economies of the Central Asian states must be taken into consideration. Key economic characteristics. Aggregate national account statistics, with official per capita gross social product figures in the range of USD 2,300-3,800 (see Table 10), would at first glance seem to provide for a rather healthy basis from which economic reform may proceed. As a guide to the economic strength of Central Asia, these figures are in all likelihood an appreciable exaggeration, however, and average per capita incomes and the share of the population eking out a living below the poverty line presumably better reflects not only the standard of living but also the relative strength of the economy. Already prior to independence and the economic decline in the past few years between 57 per cent (Kazakhstan) and 87 per cent (Tajikistan) of the population lived on less than 200 roubles per month. Table 11, outlining national income development growth rates, attests to the difficulties facing Central Asian states. Although the 1980s, at least up to 1988, provided for positive growth, subsequent retrogression has resulted in a return in the level of economic activity to the level of 1980 or earlier. 40 With an expected further decrease of 20-25 per cent in several republics in 1992, prospects are indeed bleak. Needless to say, with annual population growth rates in the range of 2 per cent or above, several of the Central Asian republics have experienced rates of even sharper decline per capita over the past few years. 40 Roland Gdtz and Uwe Halbach, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (III)', Osteuropa, Vol 42, no. 8 (1992), pp. 680-693; idem, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (IV)', Osteuropa, Vol. 42, no. 10 (1992), pp. 887-90, based on data published by Goskomstat. These statistics have, in turn, been revised downward by, for instance, 'Aggregate economic developments in the fifteen former Soviet republics, 1980-91: First release ever of comprehensive national income statistics', PlanEcon Report, Vol. VIII, nos. 11-12-13 (1992). Table 10 Economic key data Azerbaijan Gross social product, 1989 total, bn USD per capita, USD Av. per capita income 1989, ruble X below poverty line41 Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan Tajikistan Turkmenistan Uzbekistan 26.3 3 750 61.4 3 720 13.0 3 030 11.9 2 340 11.8 3 370 54.7 2 750 2 100 2 472 1 884 1 476 1 872 1 716 71 57 75 87 78 82 0.2 2.1 0.3 0.15 0.3 0.2 0.6 11.9 2.3 0.8 9.3 1.3 66 141 61 16 20 21 Arable land/capita, ha Agricultural land/capita, ha Cereal prod, as X of consumption, 1988 Sources: Roland Gdtz and Uwe Halbach, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (HI)', Osteuropa, Vol. 42, no. 8 (1992), pp. 680-693; idem, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (IV)*, Osteuropa, Vol. 42, no. 10 (1992) pp. 887-907. The figures in Table 11 do not auger well for the future of local labour absorption capacities. Assuming an employment elasticity of 0.5 (which would be rather high by Asian standards), the annual rate of real economic growth required to absorb the net increase of the working age population (as given in Table 8 above) would have to be in the range of 5-7 per cent over an extended period of time.42 Clearly, economic growth rates of this magnitude are nowhere to be seen. There41 This source states the poverty line to have been 200 roubles per month in 1989. Other have, perhaps more realistically, given lower figures and the share of the population subsiding on an income below this line should be adjusted downward accordingly. 42 On the Asian experience, see, e.g., Rashid Amjad, The development of labour intensive industry in ASEAN countries - An overview", in Rashid Amjad (ed.), The Development of Labour Intensive Industry in ASEAN Countries (Geneva: ILO/Asian Employment Programme, 1981), pp. 1-28, at p. 14 and elsewhere; and Employment and Structural Change in Pakistan - Issues for the Eighties: A report for the Pakistan Planning Commission for the Sixth Five Year Plan (1983-88) ([Bangkok:] ILO-ARTEP, 31 fore, viewed from this perspective, there is a very strong argument for the promotion of labour intensive development (i.e., an increase of the elasticity of employment) so as to compensate for the large number of entrants onto the labour market. Although it is possible to make the argument that the countries in Central Asia differ with respect to their prospects for economic growth, the well-endowed states of Kazakhstan and Turkmenistan being much favoured in this regard, it should be kept in mind that a natural resource based expansion of the economy is typically associated with low employment elasticities. Overall, it would seem that the economies of Central Asia are here facing a major challenge. This impression is corroborated by the experiences of the East European economies in transition, which struggle to keep up employment levels with stagnating or even contracting rather than fast growing working age populations. Table 11 Economic development: per cent change in national income Azerbaijan 1.0 3.9 0.0 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992* - 3.1 - 5.0 - 0.4 -21.8 Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan 0.8 0.0 2.0 - 0.1 5.8 0.5 12.6 - 1.7 -10.0 -20.3 - 0.9 - 5.0 -25.2 3.7 Tajikistan 2.6 - 1.7 12.2 - 1.0 - 8.9 - 9.0 n.a. Turkmenistan Uzbekistan 3.1 3.2 10.2 - 1.0 - 0.2 10.0 1.4 0.5 2.2 3.4 - 0.6 -10.5 - 0.9 -20.5 * Preliminary. Sources: Roland Gotz and Uwe Halbach, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (111)', Osteumpa, Vol. 42, no. 8 (1992), pp. 680-693; idem, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (TV)', Osteumpa, Vol. 42, no. 10 (1992) pp. 887-907; Financial Tunes, 20 January 1993. 1983), pp. 15-20. 32 Structure of employment. Not only economic development as expressed by macroeconomic aggregates are of importance. The general features of the economy prevailing throughout much of Central Asia have a profound effect on the pattern of employment as well, as is detailed in Table 12 on the structure of labour by industry and type of employer. The effects of primarily being assigned the role of a provider of raw materials under central planning is much in evidence. Compared with the other economies currently in transition, Central Asia has a lower share of the labour force engaged in industry. This may partly be attributed to the large share of mining and the extraction of fossil fuels, which is very capital intensive but absorbs little labour in the industrial sector of several of the countries (Table 13). Agriculture, on the other hand, has a larger share of the labour force than is usually the case even in centrally planned economies. Services (which here exclude wholesale and retail trade but include public administration and utilities) make up a similar, or slightly smaller, proportion of the labour force than is typically the case in other formerly centrally planned economies. Table 12 Structure of labour force by industry and type of employer (in per cent) Azerbaijan Industry (1987) Agriculture Industry Trade & transport Services 34 26 20 20 Type of employer (1991) State sector 67.6 Stock companies 3.8 et. al. Leasing, tenant 2.5 Kolchoz & 16.4 cooperative Private (farming) 9.7 Sources: Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan Tajikistan Turkmenistan Uzbekistan 23 31 24 22 34 27 18 21 42 21 17 20 41 21 18 20 38 24 17 21 75.5 66.0 57.6 55.7 62.4 2.6 9.0 1.6 ' 2.8 1.2 4.7 0.2 0.7 1.2 3.0 8.8 4.0 15.1 14.5 16.3 20.2 26.2 17.2 17.3 16.0 Roland Gotz and Uwe Halbach, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (111)', Osteuropa, Vol. 42, no. 8 (1992), pp. 680-693; idem, 'Die Nachfolgestaaten der UdSSR - kurz vorgestellt (IV)', Osteuropa, Vol. 42, no. 10 (1992), pp. 887-907. 33 The structure of employment by employing sector also shows traits characteristic of former centrally planned economies about to embark oh the transition to a market economy. State sector employment predominates, and the cooperative agricultural sector is rather sizeable, even though cash crops, such as cotton, are largely produced by state farms, that is, within the state sector. Private farming, including pre-eminently the former private plots (land reform has barely begun43), plays a particularly important role in Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan. Whether state, kolkhoz or private, agriculture obviously acts as a main repository for otherwise redundant labour. The non-agricultural, non-state sector has only begun to emerge, as is made evident by the table. Table 13 Branch structure of industry in 1985 (per cent of total commercial output) Primary industries Electricity Fuels Metallurgy Chemical, petrochemical Machine building Paper & wood Construction material Light industry Food industry Other Source: 43 Azerbaijan Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan Tajikistan 6.5 3.9 12.8 6.1 3.5 1.2 2.9 6.0 3.9 0.9 7.6 22.2 4.1 8.8 1.7 3.9 5.0 1.3 13.8 4.6 8.5 4.2 17.5 7.2 6.0 0.6 16.4 17.3 24.5 1.7 2.8 1.7 Turkmenistan Uzbekistan 4.3 24.8 0.1 5.8 3.8 4.1 4.7 5.5 15.8 1.7 3.2 6.0 4.0 4.9 6.0 5.6 20.9 27.1 16.3 18.6 28.5 30.5 47.0 19.6 39.9 13.7 39.1 17.7 0.8 0.7 0.8 0.4 0.5 0.8 Matthew Sagers, 'Regional industrial structures and economic prospects in the former USSR', Post-Soviet Geography, Vol. 33, no. 8 (1992), pp. 503-505. Gregory Gleason, 'Central Asia: Land reform and the ethnic factor', RFE/RL Research Report, Vol. 2, no. 3 (15 January 1993), pp. 28-33. 34 The above structure of employment may not have been a major concern from the point of view of employment and employment policies, had labour markets not shown signs of segmentation along ethnical lines. As shown in Table 14, the titular ethnic group makes up a smaller part of the labour force than it does in the total population (as given in Table 9). While the reason for this is largely to be found in age structure differentials among the ethnic groups of the area, it also reflects lower levels of female labour force participation as officially recorded, especially in rural areas. The non-titular groups are over-represented in industry and construction, that is the sectors where the risks of unemployment accumulate as reform proceeds, as well as in science and the predominantly urban based municipal economy. The titular ethnic groups are over-represented in agriculture, in particular, and are more than proportionally represented in education and government. They are overrepresented in trading, except in Kyrgyzstan. More significantly, Table 14 attests to the educational attainment of the indigenous population (see also Table 15), the effects of which, also after allowing for differential natural growth rates among nationalities, are clearly detectable in the increasing numbers of the titular ethnic group represented in most walks of life. The extent to which the titular nationality is under-represented in the labour force only tells part of the story. Also within the various economic sectors and branches, the labour force appears be segmented along ethnical lines. For instance, while the labour force of manufacturing industry may appear roughly in balance, it could well be the case that one ethnic group predominates in managerial and skilled positions, whereas the unskilled or semi-skilled parts of the workforce are made up by another.44 Should this be the case, it needs to be taken into account in projecting future developments and when devising appropriate policies. The propensity to migrate, in particular among Russians, in the wake of the breakdown of the Soviet Union deserves special attention as they often play a key role on the labour 44 This implication can be derived from the discussion contained in Michael Paul Sacks, 'Work force composition, patriarchy, and social change', in Robert Lewis (ed.), Geographic Perspectives on Soviet Central Asia (London: Routledge, 1992), pp. 181-207, esp. pp. 189-192. According to Sacks (p. 190), this also gives rise to a distinctive pattern where male dominance is felt in industrial occupations traditionally associated with female work and where '[tjhe female nonagrarian labor force of Central Asia has a far lower proportion of indigenous ethnicity than does the male labour force.' 35 market.45 In the short run any beneficial effects on the labour market of return migration of Russians, in the form of easing the supply pressure, is likely to be more than offset by resulting shortages of critical skills. To remove uncertainties, policies concerning the ethnic minorities and contigency plans in the case of large scale migration would be desirable. Table 14 Proportion of titular ethnic group in labour force by economic sectors, 1977 and 1987 (in per cent) Azerbaijan 1977 1987 Kazakhstan 1977 1987 Kyrgyzstan 1977 1987 Tajikistan 1977 1987 Turkmenistan Uzbekistan 1977 1987 1977 1987 All branches 71 78 24 33 33 41 45 54 45 59 51 61 Industry Agriculture* Transport & communications Construction Trade Municipal economy Health Education Science Government 58 91 69 90 13 38 21 52 15 63 25 69 35 62 48 63 34 58 53 81 38 67 53 76 66 63 75 67 69 70 58 69 74 73 78 76 20 11 21 17 25 36 17 34 28 21 29 23 38 43 25 40 28 16 23 19 32 44 20 35 35 26 34 30 46 43 27 42 45 36 52 46 33 51 23 42 57 48 61 56 50 58 31 51 40 41 47 41 48 56 35 45 48 54 65 53 62 67 48 51 44 36 63 52 52 61 31 46 55 50 66 55 64 69 39 57 77 80 60 78 * Excluding cooperative farms. Source: Trud v SSSR. StatistichesJdy sbomik (Moscow: Finansy i statistika, 1988), pp. 20,22-23. The urgency, and indeed cause, of this question converges on educational and skills levels among the population. The overall picture, as given in Table 15, indicates that important successes have been scored in this sphere over the past few decades. As long as the basic educational system manages to cope with the rapidly 45 On the declining Russian share in the total population of Central Asia proper and Russian outmigration from the area, see, e.g., Asal' Azamova, 'Dekolonizatsiya?...', and Viktor Perevedentsev, 'Hi 36 rising absolute numbers of school entrants, prospects for further educational improvements are good. Table 15 Per cent of total population over the age of 10 with more than primary education Azeris 1959 1970 1979 1985 Source: 36.0 42.4 63.5 72.5 Kazakhs 26.8 39.0 59.2 67.8 Kyrgyz 29.9 40.0 59.0 66.6 Tajiks 29.9 39.0 56.5 64.3 Turkmens 36.3 43.0 59.7 67.7 Uzbeks 31.1 41.2 61.5 68.3 LP. Zinchenko, 'Natsionalnyy sostav naseleniya SSSR', in AA. Isupova and N A Shvartsera (eds.), Vsesoyuznaya perepis naseleniya 1979 goda. Sbomik statey (Moscow. Finansy i stastistika, 1984), p. 160; 'Statisticheskie material/, Vestnik statistiki, 1986:7, p. 67. Although the younger cohorts of the urban based indigenous population by and large have reached parity with the other parts of the CIS in general secondary and tertiary training,46 problems have been noted to arise on the secondary level. Basic literacy and numerary can be assumed to have been taken care of by the expansion of primary schooling, but it is the quality and scope of secondary training which will be determining the ability of the work force to make a positive contribution to the development of the economy. Traditionally, the Soviet-type economy has emphasised vocational training, Central Asia being no exception in this regard. However, besides the charge that vocational and professional training has been of a substandard quality, concern has been voiced that the training has been too narrowly focused on the needs of the profession for which training is given.47 This implies not tsivilizovannyy iskhod?', both published in Moskovskie Novosti, 1992:41 (11 October 1992), p. 9. 46 Robert J. Kaiser, 'Social mobilization in Soviet Central Asia', in Robert Lewis (ed.), Geographic Perspectives on Soviet Central Asia (London: Routledge, 1992), pp. 251-278, reference 254-256. 47 E.g., Lubin, Labour and Nationality,-p. 114; Gregory Gleason, 'Educating for underemployment: 37 only that occupational mobility is unduly limited, but also that flexibility and the ability to keep up with the times may be inadvertently restricted. Employment, technology and factor intensity. As critical to the evaluation of current and future developments is the realisation that without properly functioning factor markets little by way of improvements can be achieved. In the face of serious supply side pressures on the labour market and the low level of geographical mobility, factor prices is a key instrument for adjusting the structure of the economy in accordance with relative scarcities. Up to the recent collapse of central planning, no mechanism to achieve this end was available. With wages and costs of capital decided by administrative fiat rather than by markets, any true reflection of relative scarcities in factor prices on the national, regional or local level would have been purely a chance phenomenon. This is readily made manifest in the utilisation of factors of production. Labour, capital and land have all been allocated in ever larger amounts to achieve ambitious physical production targets, apparently without considering trade-offs and dividends. As for capital investment, dispensed mainly from the all-union centre and as expressed in per worker allocation, the record is mixed. Kazakhstan and Turkmenistan have both been favoured over much of the post-war period (displaying figures above the all-union average), while Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan score much below the national average, with Azerbaijan and Uzbekistan falling inbetween. Since about 1970, however, the region has lost ground, in particular if population growth is taken into consideration, a possible reason being the de-emphasis on large scale agricultural projects.48 Nevertheless, investments in irrigation and the opening of new land to cash crop production has continued apace,49 while in Central Asia The Soviet vocational education system and its Central Asian critics', Central Asian Survey, Vol. 4, no. 1 (1985), pp. 59-81. 48 Liebowitz, 'Soviet geographical imbalances', Table 53 at p. 115. Recalculating the same data on a per capita basis (Table 5.4, p. 115) provides the author with much the same picture, now at a lower level The favoured position of Kazakhstan and Turkmenistan, in particular, are much eroded by the ten-year period beginning in the mid 1970s. 49 Peter R. Craumer, 'Agricultural change, labor supply and rural out-migration in Soviet Central Asia', in Robert Lewis (ed.), Geographic Perspectives on Soviet Central Asia (London: Routiedge, 1992), pp. 132-180. 38 proper industrial sector activities have received less attention (except in Turkmenistan, where the opportunity of natural gas exploitation has attracted centrally allocated investments).50 This pattern is borne out by the rather dismal record of labour absorption and mechanisation in the primary sector. Although earlier often perceived as a Central Asian success story,51 cotton production, which forms the backbone of agriculture in Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan, has been expanded at high levels of direct outlays. A two-pronged strategy of mechanisation and the expansion of irrigated cotton land has been the predominant attributes of the effort to increase output.52 Thus, since the late 1950s a policy of mechanisation has been pursued, with a particular emphasis on the production of cash crops, the rationale being the prospects of lower unit costs. This has not turned out to be particularly successful, with lower unit costs only seldom achieved and then often at the expense of quality, but the important point is that it was done regardless of the nature of and likely future trends in local factor endowment. An instructive example is the attempt to induce farms to employ mechanised methods by differentiating procurement prices in favour of cotton harvested by mechanical means (despite the adverse impact this may have on the quality of the cotton). In response, it is reported, although in reality picked by manual labour, some farms claimed that their cotton was indeed harvested by modern harvesters.53 Although labour inputs also have increased, this has been done with an eye on plan indicators of production rather than with a view to achieve an optimal mix of labour and capital in that production. Thus, despite the considerable expansion of 50 Ibid., p. 118. 51 E.g., by Azizur Rahman Khan and Dharam Ghai, Collective Apiculture and Rural Development in Soviet Asia: A study prepared for the International Labour Office within the framework of the World Employment Programme (London: Macmillan, 1979), pp. 62-64. 52 Developments in the production of other cash crops (such as tobacco in Kyrgyzstan) have essentially been variations on a similar theme. 53 Gregory Gleason, 'Marketization and migration: The politics of cotton in Central Asia', Journal of Soviet Nationalities, Vol. 1, no. 2 (1990), pp. 66-98. 39 employment, only a trickle of the new entrants into the labour market have been absorbed.54 The expansion of irrigated crop land mitigated any displacement of workers that would otherwise have been necessary, but this was achieved at great investment outlays and with little improvement of productivity. The intensification of the use of land (i.e., increasing labour input per unit of agricultural land) might have been a favoured strategy on the private plot, but decidedly not in state or kolkhoz agriculture. Without clear signals to the effect that labour was becoming more abundant relative other factors of production, previously favoured strategies designed to increase mechanisation and to boost agricultural production were continued as if little had happened. All in all, cash crop production has been expanded by an ever increasing deployment of labour, capital as well as land, despite rapidly diminishing returns on the margin. There is therefore considerable scope for improvements in this regard, but above all it points to the need of establishing efficient markets for factor inputs, lest the wrong signals will help maintain an inoptimal mix of factors of production, and for comprehensive agricultural sector policy reviews. d) Conclusion: Limited room for manoeuvre As the Central Asian countries embark on the fundamental economic and societal restructuring that inevitably follows from the transition towards a market economy and the breakup of the Soviet Union they face four major constraints which must have a strong imprint on policy formulation and on the design of overall development strategies. First and foremost, the Central Asian countries are all confronted with a rapid growth of their labour forces. Even under the previous economic regime, they were characterised as labour surplus regions. In contrast to the situation elsewhere in the former Soviet Union, there was open unemployment in urban areas and widespread underemployment in the agricultural sector. The young population structure implies that the labour force will continue to grow at a rapid rate over the next decades Malle, Employment Planning, pp. 37-38. 40 even if birth rates decline and overall population growth is brought under control. Productive employment generation will inevitably be a key development issue, as the strong supply side pressure on the labour market will not abate for a long time. The crucial importance of the employment issues is further underscored by the second constraints facing all the Central Asian countries, with the possible exception of Kazakhstan, namely the high population pressure on land. The scarce and environmentally damaged land resources imply inter alia that agriculture cannot, even temporarily, be relied upon to serve as an employment buffer. Although there undoubtedly is scope for increased efficiency in the utilisation of the available land resources, incremental employment generation must inevitably be concentrated to the non-farm sectors of the economies. This will be a major challenge in the years ahead and will require the full attention of policy-makers and planners and needs to be in the focus of technical assistance. A third major constraint is the unbalanced trade structure and the large deficits in foreign trade. Except for Kazakhstan (and possibly, within a reasonable time horizon, Turkmenistan), none of the countries are even close to balancing their trade with the rest of the world, at the same time as they are extremely trade dependent. Although a shift to world market prices in trade with the rest of the former Soviet Union and a gradual shift towards increased trade with non-CIS countries is likely to improve the overall terms of trade for most, if not all, of the Central Asian countries, this alone is unlikely to solve the problem of the trade deficit, at least not in the short and medium term perspective. The Central Asian countries urgently need to focus their attention on developing their export base and to develop new markets for their exports. In many instances this is likely to be any up-hill struggle. Economic diversification and increased self-sufficiency is no substitute for trade, in particular as, except for Kazakhstan, all the countries register large deficits in food production. Thus circumstances would seem to leave no option but strong emphasis on export-oriented, employment-based development strategies. Qualitative development and enhanced and more efficient utilisation of the countries' human resources need therefore become key development objectives. A fourth constraint is the precarious budgetary situation of most of the governments concerned and, more broadly, the generally weak capacity to formulate 41 and implement policies. Loss of revenue following from a discontinuation of the previous financial net flow from the central government to the republican administrations within the former Soviet Union and revenue losses following from the transition process imply not only that new sources of revenue need to be developed, but also that, at least in the near term future, policy implementation in the Central Asian countries will be subject to severe financial constraints and will need to meet very high requirements of cost-efficiency. In some of the countries (e.g., Turkmenistan, Kazakhstan) there would seem to exist good prospects for enhanced generation of government revenues, primarily from exploitation of natural resources, while in others (viz. Uzbekistan and Tajikistan) no easy solutions are in sight. 42 IV. A policy agenda Since the Central Asian countries obtained independence in the second half of 1991 they have all opted for a policy of gradual economic liberalisation and transformation. The aim has been to strike a balance between the need for fundamental economic reform and restructuring on the one hand and theriskof increasing economic disorder and political and social unrest on the other hand. The recent statement by the president of Turkmenistan, Saparmurad Niyazov, that '[w]e shall maintain a balance between the desired and the possible as we are making headway toward a market system'55 is representative in this regard. During the first year after the collapse of the Soviet Union the main concern has inevitably been to counter and mitigate as far as possible the economic disarray and slump in production that followed in its trail and to cope with the acute problems of nation building. As the economic links with Russia remain intimate, not least through continued membership in the ruble zone (although Azerbaijan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan have taken steps to establish their own currencies), the room for independent macro-economic policies remain limited. Thus, the countries have inter alia had to accept that the pace of price liberalisation has by and large been set in Moscow. Considerable preparatory work for a privatisation of the economy has been undertaken in all of the countries. Privatisation plans have been drafted and much of the legislation is now in place. However, implementation will inevitable be difficult and slow. Already, fear of rampant unemployment and the economic slump is showing signs of slowing down the often ambitious plans for marketisation of enterprises, viz. in Kyrgyzstan.56 Similarly, all the countries in the region have adopted land reform programmes, aiming at transfering the managerial and usufruct rights, but not necessarily the ownership, of agricultural land to the individual farm households. However, implementation in this area, too, has so far been slow and piecemeal. Despite attempts at liberalisation, state control over agricultural production remains large and, for example in Uzbekistan, artificially low state procurement 55 56 Ecotass, 1993:6 (25 January 1993). Bess Brown, 'Central Asia: The first year of unexpected statehood', RFE/RL Research Report, Vol. 2, no.l (1 January 1993), pp. 25-36; Cassandra Cavanaugh, 'Uzbekistan's long road to the market', RFE/RL Research Report, Vol. 1, no. 29 (17 July 1992), pp. 33-38. 43 prices in the face of sharp increases in the prices of agricultural inputs have deteriorated agricultural terms-of-trade. Although unemployment rates are rising in all the countries and the danger of large scale unemployment looms large on the horizon, by early 1993 it had only assumed acute proportions in Uzbekistan, where unofficial estimates placed the number at almost two million.57 Employment policies have so far shown a bias towards passive policies, although the employment funds established in all the countries, except Turkmenistan, generally have a mandate to engage in job placement and training as well as in disbursement of unemployment benefits. While the establishment of the employment funds are a laudable step forward, this initiative does not amount to a full-fledged employment strategy and is, by itself, inadequate as response to the emerging employment problems. Indeed, a main conclusion of the review of the issues and problems confronting the Central Asian countries is that the employment aspects are of absolutely paramount importance as these newly independent countries begin to chart their course ahead. The young population structures imply that the economies will need to absorb large increments in the labour force on top of those who are displaced and need alternative employment as a consequence of the transition process. At the same time, the structure of the economies make them ill-suited to assume this task, while poorly developed factor markets impair labour market flexibility and spontaneous growth processes. However, rather than being seen as a development problem, the young and growing labour forces should be taken as the main resource for development in the design of strategies for structural change and growth. Such employment based development strategies will need to address both the issue of upgrading the quality of the human capital and, in particular, increasing the efficiency in its utilisation. To this end a three-pronged approach to confronting the employment issues facing the Central Asian countries may be identified. The first and most important component should be to ensure an effective integration of the employment aspects into overall economic development strategies and policies for structural change and transition to market oriented economies. This point needs to be made with some force, as it by and large implies a break with past Cavanaugh, 'Uzbekistan's long road', as compared to 600,000 officially registered unemployed. 44 practices and requires that policy-makers and planners are imbued with a new mode of thinking. Furthermore, the states in these countries are weak and the temptation to replace dogmatic belief in the plan by a similarly unquestioning belief in the market presents a real danger, in particular as markets are for the most part not yet in place. Irrespective of the political and economic ideology adopted, the state will need to continue to play an active and major role in the economy in the forseeable future and a policy of laissez-faire does not present a viable alternative to forcefully pursued development strategies. Restructuring the economies with a view to diversify the economic base and rectify the biases towards large scale heavy industry, and industry over services, will have fundamental, potentially positive, employment implications. Sound macroeconomic and trade policies, the creation of an environment conducive to the development and growth of new enterprises and forceful regional policies are three broad areas for strategies to encourage and guide the restructuring of the economies. Policies of a more general nature need to be combined with more specifically targeted policies, requiring an assessment of each country's comparative advantages and clearly formulted objectives. It may be conceptually useful to distinguish the countries that are rich in energy and natural resources - Kazakhstan, Azerbaijan and Turkmenistan - from the other three: Kyrgyzstan, Tadjikistan and Uzbekistan. The rich endowment with natural resources makes the former countries attractive targets for foreign direct investments58 and hold promises of enhanced earnings of foreign exchange and of government revenues. While such a development may provide an escape from the current impasse, it is by itself unlikely to have any major effect on employment generation. Mining and extraction of natural resources provides neither much employment nor does it have any significant linkages effects. On the contrary, a development based on extraction and export of energy and other raw materials carries the risk of 'Dutch disease',59 in particular as the absorptive capacities of these 58 In particular Kazakhstan has already attracted considerable attention among foreign investors; see Ahmed Rashid, The next frontier: Kazakhstan is a magnet for energy firms', Far Eastern Economic Review, 4 February 1993, pp. 48-50. 59 The 'Dutch disease' refers to the effects of windfall gains (e.g., from rapidly increasing exports from a booming sector or from development assistance) on (i) the exchange rate • the national currency being appreciated - and (ii) costs of production, which tend to rise also in non-booming sectors, 45 economies are limited and factor markets function poorly. Thus, the main risk would seem to be that successes in exploiting natural resources and in generating foreign exchange may cloud the need for economic diversification and employmentbased growth. The second tier of countries appear less lustrous in the eyes of foreign investers and face the starker problem of achieving economic development and increasing employment and income generation with limited resources at hand and in the face of tight foreign exchange and budgetary constraints. Employment aspects also need to be incorporated in the strategy for achieving the transition to market economies. Price liberalisation, fiscal and monetary policies, trade policies, development of factor markets, privatisation and, not least, de-collectivisation of agriculture, have important implications on employment and incomes. Yet, as noted above, policies in this field in East Central Europe have typically been formulated and implemented without consideration of the employment aspects. As late starters, the Central Asian countries can benefit from the experiences of other transition economies and need not repeat this mistake. As a consequence of independence and the change of economic system the government administrative apparatuses are being remolded. This provides a unique opportunity to ensure that employment aspects are administratively integrated into the planning process. Ideally, an employment and manpower planning unit may be established, attached to a key ministry and with direct communication channels with other ministries and key organisations and backed up by a small research outfit. This would serve the purpose of concentrating scarce competence, ensure integration of employment aspects into overall planning, break down intersectoral/ministerial barriers to communication and create national focal points for external assistance and regional cooperation. A system for monitoring and forecasting changes in the supply and demand for labour and appearances of critical skills needs to be developed to remedy the current scarcity of quantitative information and in light of the volatile changes that follow in the trail of economic transition. Innovative approaches are needed to devise a thereby effectively reducing the competitiveness of the latter. See William L. Corden and Peter Neary, 'Booming sector and de-industrialization in a small open economy*, Economic Journal, Vol. 92, no. 368 (1982), pp. 825-848. 46 system which is capable of collecting and processing information quickly and which makes maximum use of inadequate statistical information. It should be noted in this context that short and long term forecasting requires different approaches and that regional aspects are important. Apart from inadequate statistical information, the knowledge base on employment related issues remains patchy and partly out of date. Investigative studies in a variety of areas will be required to fill information gaps and provide an adequate base for policy formulation. In view of the inappropriate policies and untenable development patterns in agriculture, and the large and rapidly increasing labour force in rural areas, studies aimed at providing a basis for new agricultural strategies and identification of avenues for increasing the labour absorptive capacity of the rural economy deserve special priority. Other obvious topics for studies include promotion of entrepreneurship and small scale enterprise development in general and the employment aspects of policies for economic transition. Mechanisms for regional cooperation and, in particular, exchange of information need to be developed. Given the unfamiliar and experimental situation, much can be gained from a regular exchange of information between the Central Asian countries, but also by learning from the experiences of more advanced transition economies in East Central Europe and from China and Vietnam. Regional cooperation would also facilitate pooling of resources, for example in research and specialised training (in particular as language barriers between most Central Asian countries are small). ILO is well placed to provide technical assistance and advisory services in all the • above areas. Apart from supplementing scarce local expertise, it has a key role to play in providing access to the vast body of experience in employment planning generated in other countries - which is neither well-known nor easily accesible to policymakers in the region - and by acting as a catalyst for international cooperation. The latter is particularly important in view of the rather weak traditional links between the Central Asian countries on the one hand and transition economies elsewhere on the other hand. Advisory services are also needed to make up for the limited domestic experiences in the formulation and implementation of employment 47 policies in a market based economic system. The second component on the policy agenda should focus on active labour market policies. As noted above, the initial response to the emerging problems of unemployment in the transition economies in East Central Europe has primarily taken the form of traditional passive labour market policies. Such an approach is. both inadequate and unsustainable. Drastic changes in both the demand and the supply of labour in the wake of commercialisation and marketisation of state enterprises, economic restructuring and return migration of, primarily, Russians need to be matched by efficient labour markets and high labour mobility. Unfortunately, the Central Asian countries have inherited a legacy of inadequate labour market institutions and low labour mobility, to which may be added ethnically segregated labour markets. The main areas for policies include the creation of an institutional framework for efficient labour intermediation, a review of labour legislation, a shift from administrative wage determination to a modern system of wage bargaining, and revamping of the system for professional and vocational training (and re-training) with a view to increase the vocational mobility of labour. The establishment of employment funds in five of the six countries under study can be seen as constituting an important first step in this direction. In addition, the possibility of initiating public works programmes and other direct employment creating schemes as an alternative to dispensing unemployment benefits deserves serious investigation. Such programmes may be initiated within the frame of public investments in physical infrastructure and should then be co-ordinated with regional and rural development policies. Geographical decentralisation of economic activities and diversification of the economic base in rural areas and small towns will inevitably require considerably investments in physical infrastructure. Efficient intermediation of labour requires a network of labour exchanges/ placement bureaus. Under the old system most hirings were done directly by the enterprises.60 In the 1970s a network of job placement bureaus were established 60 In the whole Soviet Union the percentage of hirings done directly by the enterprises fell from 79 per cent in 1971 to 62 per cent in 1981 (Malle, Employment Planning, p. 62). By 1991, an estimated 43 million individuals, or 22 per cent out of a total of 19.5 million jobs allocated, found work with the help of employment bureaus, according to Aleksandr Shokhin, 'Labour market regulation in the USSR', Communist Economies and Economic Transformation, Vol. 3, no. 4 (1991), pp. 499-509, at p. 500. 48 throughout the country in response to perceived increasing labour shortages. However, the main objective of these bureaus was to mobilise labour in an overall environment of labour shortage rather than to serve as institutions for genuine labour intermediation.61 Thus, this network (which has offices in all larger cities) will need to be given a different mandate and will also require assistance to assume the task of promoting labour mobility and providing intermediation between employers and job seekers in a market environment. Ideally, they should also be redesigned to play an additional role as collection points of labour market information; such as changes in the supply and demand for specific skills, wage levels and the development of shortages of critical skills. Major revisions of the educational and training systems are likely to be required. The Soviet educational system needs to be reviewed to determine to what extent it is still appropriate and what changes are needed. The qualitative aspects deserve particular attention in view of the widespread critisism, particularly with regard to rural education. The system for vocational and skills training need to be revamped. It would appear that it never functioned very well in the first place62 and the change of economic system will render it partly obsolete. An overhaul of the training system should be undertaken against the backdrop of the changes in the economic structure and would inter alia result in a much stronger emphasis on training in entrepreneurship and rudimentary business administration as a complement to skills training. Channels of communication need also be developed between the central agency responsible for employment and manpower planning and the training institutes. In addition to traditional training, it may be expected that there will be a considerable need for short term retraining of skilled labour, and of upgrading of skill levels among adults. The existing labour and wage legislation is both inadequate and largely inappropriate to meet the needs of a pluralistic market economy. As already noted the old system of administrative wage determination needs to be replaced by a modern system of wage bargaining. A careful balance needs to be struck between 61 62 Malle, Employment Planning, p. 68. See for example Gleason, 'Educating for underemployment', and Yevgeni Antosenkov, 'A new employment concept in Soviet labour legislation', in Guy Standing (ed.), In Search of Flexibility: The new Soviet labour market (Geneva: ILO, 1991), pp. 63-79, especially pp. 73-78. 49 the need for a flexible and market based wage system, which is essential for the establishment of an efficient labour market, and equity aspects. Thus, the guiding principle should be to foster direct links between the supply and demand for labour and wage levels, at the same time as certain safeguards are established for the weaker segments of the labour force and outright exploitatory practices are prevented. As all the Central Asian countries face the same need to revise the legislative framework and the system of wage determination, and as there is considerable prior experience from other countries, this is an obvious area for technical assistance and regional cooperation. Indeed, these are all traditional areas for ILO technical assistance and advisory services, but they are essentially uncharted territories for the new to the governments in the Central Asian countries. Much can be learnt by the experiences of others in these fields and by pooling and drawing on the experiences of other transition economies large synergy effects can be gained and the quality of the assistance provided enhanced. Lastly, as a third component, a social security net needs to be developed to fill the void left behind by the defunct centrally planned economic system. Poverty levels in most of the Central Asian countries were alarmingly high already prior to independence and the situation has worsened over the past few years. Budgetary constraints impose severe limitations on the comprehensiveness and level of ambition of social security schemes. The main task must therefore be to devise costefficient schemes that are well-targeted on those in greatest need of assistance and to ensure that the schemes are financially sustainable. Not least the trial and error approach adopted by several of the formerly socialist countries in East Central Europe highlight the gains that can be made from learning from the experiences of others in this field. LABOUR MARKET ANALYSIS AND EMPLOYMENT PLANNING Working Papers WP. 1 Labour markets, labour processes and economic development: Some research issues by Gerry Rodgers. September 1985 WP.2 The work experience programme in Ireland by Richard Breen, March 1986 WP.3 Labour flexibility: Towards a research agenda by Guy Standing, April 1986 WP.4 Quantitive techniques for employment planning: supply by Stan Stavenuiter, June 1986 WP.5 Socio-economic analysis and planning within a social accounting framework by Jan Vandemoortele, June 1986 WP.6 A model for short term economic policy, employment and incomes - Peru, 1983 by Norberto E. Garcia, June 1986 WP.7 Manpower planning and employment issues in developing countries by Rashid Amjad and Christopher Colclough, June 1986 WP.8 Studies on labour market modelling and employment planning in Central America by Ricardo Infante and Guillermo Garcia-Huidobro. June 1986 WP.9 Aspects of governmental job creation efforts in Western Europe and North America by Robinson G. Hollister, Jr., September 1986 WP. 10 Some techniques for regionalised long-term planning of the size and structure of employment in Yugoslavia by Bojan Popovic, December 1985 WP.ll MACBETH: A model for forecasting population, education, manpower, employment, underemployment and unemployment by Michael Hopkins. Luis Crouch and Scott Moreland. September 1986 WP.12 Developments in the analysis and planning of labour and manpower by S.I. Cohen. September 1986 ' V : .13 Vulnerable groups in urban labour processes by Guy Standing, May 1987 WP.14 Flexibility and American labour markets: The evidence and implications by Richard Belous. June 1987 WP. 15 Employment trends in the United States by Ronald E. Kutscher. July 1987 Applications to labour surplus .16 Working time reductions as an employment generating tool: A survey by Roberto Zachmann, July 1987 WP.17 The dark side of labour market "flexibility": Falling wages and growing income inequality in America by Bennett Harrison and Barry Bluestone. October 1987 WP.18 Rural-urban income trends in sub-Saharan Africa by Vali Jamal and John Weeks. November 1987 WP.19 Le Bilan des contrats Emploi-formation en France, 1975-1985 par Marie-Laurence Caspar, octobre 1987 WP.20 The experience with youth employment programmes in the United States by Professor Robinson G. Hollister, Jr., March 1988 WP.21 Youth employment and institutional arrangements in Australia by Robert Kyloh. May 1988 WP.22 Good jobs or bad jobs: What does the US evidence say? by Gary W. Loveman and Chris Tilly, June 1988 WP.23 European unemployment, insecurity and flexibility: (updated version) by Guy Standing, April 1989 WP.24 Flexibility in the Bombay labour market by L.K. Deshpande, August 1988 WP.25 The informalisation of employment: Child labour in urban industries of India by Neera Burra. August 1988 WP.26 Manpower requirements models: A synthesis by Berhanu Abegaz, September 1988 WP.27 African public sector retrenchment: An analytical survey by Paul Collier. November 1988 WP.28 Partage des profits et marche" du travail en France par Daniel Vaughan-Whitehead. avril 1989 WP.29 An overview and comparative, analysis of special employment programmes in developed and developing countries by David H. Freedman, April 1989 WP.30 Work organisation and local lab. .ir markets in an era of flexible production by Michael Storper and Allen J. icott. June 1989 WP.31 Global feminisation through flexible labour by Guy Standing, June 1989 WP.32 Urban labour markets in India bv Swapna Mukhopadhyay. June 1989 v_ A social dividend solution .33 How can the manpower planning debate be resolved? by Christopher Golclough, July 1989 WP.34 Umemployment and labour segmentation, the growing challenges of the Italian model by Loretta de Luca, October 1989 WP.35 The growth of external labour flexibility in a nascent NIC: The Malaysian Labour Flexibility Survey (MLFS) by Guy Standing, November 1989 WP.36 Conditions of labour in the small-scale and unorganised sectors in Calcutta and its neighbourhood by Robin Mukherjee, January 1990 WP.37 An analysis of the Australian consensual incomes policy: The prices and incomes accord by Bruce J. Chapman and Fred Gruen, May 1990 WP.38 Self-employment in industrialised market economy countries by F. J. Bayliss, May 1990 WP.39 Urban self-employment in Hungary by L. HtSthy, May 1990 WP.40 Crisis management in employment planning: The Indonesian case by Martin Godfrey, June 1990 WP.41 L'auto-emploi urbain en Algfrie par Chantal Bernard, juillet 1990 WP.42 Self-employment in Ecuador and Mexico by Gilda Farrell. July 1990 WP.43 Urban self-employment in Senegal by Harold LubelL July 1990 WP.44 Labour surplus and labour shortage in the USSR by Vladimir G. Kostakov. August 1990 WP.45 The promotion of self-employment and small-scale enterprises in urban Kenya: A case study by William J. House. Gerrishon K. Ikiaraand Dorothy McCormick, September 1990 WP.46 Economic adjustment, pay structure and the problem of incentives in Eastern European countries by Gyorgy Szirdczki, December 1990 WP.47 Do unions impede or accelerate structural adjustment? Industrial versus company unions in an industrialising-labour market by Guy Standing, December 1990 WP.48 The distinctive pattern of non-agricultural self-employment in Italy by Aureio Parisotto. April 1991 WP.49 Employment and retrenchment in the public sector by Iqbal Ahmed, April 1991 WP.50 Structural adjustment and retrenchment in the civil service: The case of Tanzania by Ian Mamuya, April 1991 WP.51 Retrenchment and redeployment in the public sector of the Nigerian Economy by Olanrewaju J. Fapohunda, April 1991 WP.52 The labour impact of technological change in a developing country: An empirical approach by Guy Standing, 1991 VVP.53 The effects of government policies on the incentives to invest, enterprise behaviour and employment: A study of Mexico's economic reforms in the eighties by Jaime Ros WP.54 The Romanian wage system in the transition to a market economy by Catalin Zamfir WP.55 The labour market, social policy and industrial relations in the Soviet Union under transition by Alexander Samorodov, April 1992 WP.56 Recent trends in labour force participation of older persons by Robert L. Clark and Richard Anker, May 1992 WP.57 Effects of government policies on the incentive to invest, enterprise behaviour and employment: Case study of Vietnam by David H.D. Truong and Carolyn L. Gates WP.58 Youth employment and remedial programmes in Jamaica: assessment by Pauline Knight. June 1992 WP.59 External labour flexibility in Filippino industry by James Windell and Guy Standing, July 1992 WP.60 Cumulative disadvantage? Women industrial workers in Malaysia and the Philippines by Guy Standing, July 1992 WP.61 Employment and economic transtbrmation in Central Asia by Per Ronnas and Orjan Sjoberg, December 1993 WP.62 The impact of employment restructuring on disadvantaged groups in Bulgaria and Hungary by Gyorgy Sziraczki and James Windell, January 1993 WP.63 Employment Dynamics in Bulgarian Industry by Guy Standing, Gyorgy Sziraczki and James Windell, August 1993 An economy-wide WP.64 Recruitment and the Role of Employment Services in Bulgarian Industry by Guy Standing, Gyorgy Sziraczki and James Windell, August 1993 WEP Research Working Papers are preliminary documents circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. A set of selected WEP Research Working Papers, completed by annual supplements, is available in microfiche form for sale to the public: orders should be sent to ILO Publications, International Labour Office. CH-1211 Geneva 22. Switzerland. hm-g: imuctwtapap
Similar documents
Economic Transformation and Employment in Central Asia
explained by the lack of tradition and experience in the field of employment and labour market policies, but it is inadequate and likely to rapidly become unsustainable for cost reasons. Privatizat...
More information