FOREST POLICY AND TRADE: THE NEW ZEALAND EXPERIENCE
Transcription
FOREST POLICY AND TRADE: THE NEW ZEALAND EXPERIENCE
FOREST POLICY AND TRADE: THE NEW ZEALAND EXPERIENCE by Kenneth E Jackson University of Auckland On leave in Department of Economics University of Western Australia DISCUSSION PAPER 91.10 JULY 1991 ISSN 0811-6067 ISBN 0-86422-134-7 1 INTRODUCTION Officially New Zealand was a dependency of New South Wales from 1840-41 and a separate Crown Colony from 1841-1852. Even with the granting of representative Government, however, the economic status of New Zealancl, remained very much that of a dependent state. It was dependent upon the U.K. market for its trade in wool and later in the century meat and dairy products, as well as being largely dependent upon Australian markets for its trade in timber and other forest products. Whilst the former has been altered in recent times, the latter remains relatively unchanged. Government regulation and control was generally ineffective for much of the early period. Government attitudes were part of a wider ethos in favour of clearance. Little if any real concern was apparent for retaining any sizeable stock of forest. Early Conservators had unfortunate experiences, one being drowned in the period between his appointment and taking up office and another lasting only a brief period before his post disappeared in the face of financial stringency. To 1920 at least there was more rhetoric than action. Most of the settlers were probably looking for land for agricultural and pastoral purposes, rather than looking for entrepreneurial opportunities as sawmill owners. Clearance was uppermost in their minds and was encouraged and fostered by the activities of governments who subsidised it directly, as well as indirectly with their infra-structural developments. From 1853 the compilation and reporting of New Zealand's trade statistics was centralised. At this time total timber export receipts were of major significance. Their value then of £93,000 was not exceeded for another twenty nine years and it represented approximately 30 per cent of export receipts when taken together with Kauri gum, flax and other non-timber forest products. (Bloomfield 1984, 263, 271 and 279). Chart 1 displays the relative position of the principal exports over the course of the next one hundred and twenty years. Atl'v'l::l811 "'v'"f\!\ 11A. t I IC"LJ-::1/\ll\l1' ! i ~ 2 3 As the chart clearly demonstrates, the relative importance of the impact upon the state of the New Zealand timber industry. In the third international trade in timber quickly diminished after 1853. Imports of section of the paper the domestic trade in timber is briefly considered in timber were also limited, leaving the domestic trade as the dominant terms of its interaction with the international trade position, and then the factor in determining. the industry's contribution to the rate of depletion similarities with the present day South American position are considered of the natural capital stock. This domestic rate of consumption is also in section four. linked to international trade. It is the purpose of this paper to demonstrate that the introduction into the international economy of the basic, and more especially the pastoral, products of New Zealand directly affected the state of the natural capital. stock in the forests and draw some comparisons with the current Amazonian experience. It has been sugg?sted that relative to agriculture, the historical development of timber in New Zealand has been neglected (Roche 1990, 295). In the rush to count sheep perhaps drowsiness has dulled our perceptions and lecLto such neglect, but recent work such as Michael Roche's and Rollo Arnold's (1976) has at least provided a sound base from which to proceed. What follows attempts to expand and refine their contributions and demonstrates the interaction of agricultural and forest development. The impact of growth in the international trade in timber itself upon the rate of depletion of the forest resource, was limited. Nontimber trade growth, however, played an important and integral part in an explanation of how both the external and domestic timber trade developed. The paper concentrates largely on the period ending in the nineteen twenties as little addition to the area under cultivation is to be seen in the inter-war period. The sequence of this paper is to look firstly at the consequences of the international trade in timber, followed by considering the impact of the international trade in other products of the soil and their consequential 4 5 PART ONE such neglect, in maintaining that the high current level of interest in NEW ZEALAND'S INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN TIMBER conservation matters, especially a concern for indigenous forests, has worked against analytical studies. He does stress the less fanciful and "New Zealand imports practically all kinds more likely reason, that difficulty in finding source materials has been a of manufactured articles from building major contributing factor, rather than the fear of the conservationists' ire materials to soaps, and some raw materials, (Arnold, 1976, 105). Whatever the problems facing the researcher, the such as pig iron, oils and even timber" very low level of export share, at 1 or 2 per cent for much of the late- (emphasis added). nineteenth century, would appear to justify at least some of this neglect. Concentrating on exports is understandable in the sense of Arnold's lack The almost audible.tone of surprise revealed by Condliffe (1915, 860) of source material or data, since customs records exist whereas basic reveals just how embedded in New Zealand's economic history was the domestic records are somewhat more erratic, especially at the level of the thought that it was.exports that acted as the principal engine of growth in individual firm. The over-concentration upon timber exports, however, the nineteenth century. Timber played a significant role in exports from leads to the omission of the major part of the story, that of the domestic the earliest days, with pit-sawn timber being sent to New South Wales on consumption of timber at this time. This can be linked directly to the Australia's eastem; seaboard from the eighteen twenties and thirties trade situation in terms of the growth of other exports and the constant (Roche, 1990, 29TJ. demand for land for pastoral and agricultural production and for timber By 1853 timber exports, then at their zenith, accounted for approximately one third of all export receipts (Condliffe, 1915, 906). as an input into various industries. The direct contribution of timber to the export position receded rapidly from.this peak, never again reaching double figures in The general feeling that the history of timber has been neglected is terms of a percentage of all exports by value after 1854. 1860 was the correct, but the approach which sees progress solely through the eve of the gold era in New Zealand and timber exports had contracted to successive tightening of legislation and control can lead to a partial form only 2 per cent of the total receipts, subsequently fluctuating between 1 of analysis, disregarding or neglecting the possibility of other forms of and 2 per cent through to the outbreak of World War One (Condliffe, change. The eventual appearance of the Forest Service can be seen as the 1915, 906-907). culmination of this march of progressive interventionism. Failure in the early legislation is seen almost as sufficient evidence that what was This rapid decline in export share has led to much neglect of the role of needed was more of the same, or more effective forms of it, rather than forests in New Zealand's economic development. The timber industry asking if there were really other causes of difficulty. Other causes such receives but scant attention in most works concerned with the expansion as general export growth did exert some influence, with some of the of settlement. Rollo Arnold produced a rather imaginative argument for interventionist activities working against, rather than for the cause of any 6 rational approach to the forest 7 Kauri was a threatened species by the early twentieth century and part at least of the blame for this can be laid at the timber industry's door. Of It would appear that the direct demand for timber exports exerted only a the total milling resources at the end of World War One, only about one very limited impact upon the level of the natural capital stock in an half of one per cent was Kauri (Neale, 1925, 322). Saw millers were aggregate sense, but it may have been significant in terms of the demand apparent rent seekers who encouraged the acquisition of government for specific species with consequent impacts upon the mix of indigenous protection from imports and discouraged any fledgling ideas of forest. Kauri timber was the main component of exports before 1914, conservation such as the attempt at export taxes to protect the forests with Kahikatea being used for the specific purpose of packaging for butter noted in 1915 by Condliffe (Condliffe, 1915, 912). Exports by this stage and cheese due to its non-tainting qualities (Roche, 1990, 302). Australia were dwindling in any case, as can be seen from the accompanying formed the basic market for exports of such timbers, since it was only in graphs. The story of the inter-war years is one of a declining export trade the inter-war period that Britain really started to consider such far-flung from a 1920 value peak ending a short post-war boom and a 1915 volume outposts of Empire as part of its potential source of supplies and even peak (Bloomfield, 1984, 281). By 1921 Imports had moved ahead of then only to a very limited extent. Transport costs were sufficient to Exports by value (Neale, 1925, 322) and New Zealand was viewed as an preclude earlier or greater consideration. unlikely source of future supplies by Britain. The Reconstruction Committee report of 1917-18 wrote off New Zealand, along with The larger firms were dominant in the New Zealand export trade and they Australia, India, and South Africa as potential suppliers. (Acland, 1918, were centred on the Auckland region. By 1881 over 90 per cent of 19). Only small amounts of Kauri, Rimu and Totara found their way into timber exports by value were leaving through Auckland ports (Stone, Britain in the nineteen twenties (Stobart, 1927, 31). 1973, 93) and the vast majority of these exports were of Kauri. The market, Australia, remained the dominant customer taking some 98 per timber industry appeared set on a course of rapid cutting, but its business cent of timber exports (Neale, 1925, 322). Little wonder that the biggest decisions and their consequent impacts were largely the result of the industrial combination ever to operate in the early industry, the Kauri institutional background they worked against. New Zealand was not a Timber Company, had extensive financial, market and other links with conservation conscious society in the late-nineteenth century. The social Australia. The traditional costs of forest clearance were relatively neglected in a push for agricultural and pastoral expansion. If pastoral produce prices rose, the It is the decade of the eighteen nineties that is crucial in determining the incentive to clear land rose, more timber was therefore available for role timber exports played in the deforestation process. At this time of immediate cutting, reducing the likelihood of any conservation through greatest activity in forest clearances, the level of exports as can be seen increased price. in the charts, was actually falling away, only recovering to 1888-91 levels Government policy hastened this process, thereby assisting in the rapid demise of the virgin forest. and above by 1899. The eighteen nineties saw a 14,000 square mile 8 9 decrease in the forested area, the maximum of any decade and up from stationery as a category represented between 4 and 5 per cent of the total the 6,000 square miles cleared in the course of the previous decade value of imports by the early twentieth century (Condliffe, 1915, 914-5). (Condliffe, 1959, 3). Not only was the level of exports not rising in Comparative cost advantages probably determined this to be an commensurate fashion to the increased rate of depletion, it was actually appropriate form of trade, but did not prevent complaints from those static if not declining, with the collapse of the Melbourne residential seeking conservation, who saw only waste and burning of the local construction boom in the early nineties removing a large part of the export timber. There are surprised comments regarding the existence of imports demand. The subsequent pick up in exports in the twentieth century, of timber whilst burning for clearance was widespread (Fleet, 1984, 81). which peaked in 1912, represents only a doubling of the 1890 level of Such action may or may not have been economically appropriate, no-one demand, not enough to satisfactorily account for the rapacious clearance appears to have properly studied the question, either then or since. rates obviously continuing at this time, with 1895-1914 seeing almost half as much additional land again brought into cultivation as in all New 1908 saw a pre-war peak in imports of 51,000,000 super feet, more than Zealand's previousbistory. (Simkin, 1951, 169). Milling for export does double the amount imported in any previous year (Beasley, 1930, 28). At not provide a satisfactory answer for the rapid rate of depletion, except for this peak imports constituted more than I 0 per cent of the total domestic the specific case of,Kauri, and even then the answer is only a partial one. consumption, but this was the only year before 1914 that they achieved Other factors contributed to Kauri's demise apart from the international such a high level. Normally they were at minimal levels before 1900, timber export trade. essentially confined to specific hardwoods such as Ironwood and Jarrah and other timbers difficult to obtain locally, along with small supplies of Possible responsibility could still rest with the industry through milling for Douglas Fir, known locally as Oregon Pine (Neale, 1925, 322). domestic purposes, but before considering that something must be said of the import position, since imports could have substituted for local After World War One imports climbed to a peak in the late twenties and production. Until the nineteen twenties, imports remained low. Only a declined sharply thereafter through to 1934. Their overall value remained small portion of the total timber used domestically came from abroad. slight in relation to all imports and their contribution in terms of reducing Imports of timber do not rate a mention in the general trade statistics as the impact on the local forest of meeting the demands of domestic and a significant entry for the early period, except in a manufactured or value general export expansion was very limited. Suggestions that in the inter- added form. Condliffe commented that despite having timber found war period the domestic price level was set below the export price (Carter, suitable for paper-making, all the paper used was imported from England 1972, 189-90) by controls suggests continuing foolishness in intervention, and Canada. (Condliffe, 1915, 867). Kauri was exported for furniture if forest destruction was to be avoided. making some of which, along with any exported fibre going into paper, might be returned to New Zealand in its manufactured state. Paper and 10 11 PART TWO of agriculture and pastoralism as the main business in hand. EXPORT EXPANSION AND DOMESTIC ACTIVITY. By the close of the nineteenth century it is clear that the New Zealand The export trade in timber has generally been accepted as not being the forest was suffering from an attitude to "the bush" that saw it as a barrier, prime cause of deforestation in New Zealand. The results of Part One's an encumbrance to be removed. investigation would<tend to confirm such an opinion. Writers as diverse pastoral products that formed the basis of the land based economy. The as Condliffe (1959; 134-5), Horgan (1990, 1), Searle (1975, 30), and farming sector was reputed to produce not just most of the exports, but Roche (1990, 299Yhave all concluded that the extension of agricultural 60 per cent of all national output by 1900-1. Forestry in all its forms, and pastoral settlement was the root cause of deforestation. including Kauri Gum for varnish, fungi and other non-timber products Several observers have suggested in the past that the industry and government In terms of export receipts it was totalled only some 6 per cent. (Simkin, 1951, 177). regulation made things worse rather than better by wasteful use of the resource and by distorting the price structure through intervention. These There is a lack of definitive figures as to timber's share of Gross effects were visible and were generally antipathetic to conserving the Domestic Product. Measures such as employment, capital employed and forest. Whether or not they would greatly have affected the eventual output in physical terms reveal it to be a major player in the outcome is open to some debate. Government encouragement to manufacturing sector, but a bit-part performer in the wider sense. Even clearance through "improvement leases" (N.Z.O.Y.B., 1914, 512-3) at 6 per cent of G.D.P. the timber industry, would represent a significant shortened the time available to exploit timber since improvement required but relatively small component of the whole. clearance. Subsidising rail transport for timber reduced costs in particular areas, probably didno more than allow a greater use of timber that would The role played in deforestation by the domestic timber industry was otherwise have been burnt. larger than that of its export counterpart. Domestic output levels between 3 to 3 1/2 times those of export volumes appear to have been the normal Direct efforts at conserving timber stocks were evident, but limited before order of magnitude at the end of the nineteenth century. This includes 1914. Prices charged for royalties varied with the major changes outlined none of the output put through small mills or roughly processed for use in Chart 3. Until 1921 royalties were essentially charged, not on standing in the bush (tramways etc.) or on farms, only that passing through the timber but on mill output (Conway, 1974, 8) and there was disguising of major mill establishments. Firewood represents another missing item. public as private timber, where both were being milled, so that royalties could be avoided. There was also different treatment for timber licences The consequent impact on the forest resource of the home "milling" in mining areas, a problem not fully redressed until 1949 (Kirkland & industry is therefore far larger than that of the export markets. It was Trotman, 1974, 1) and a general preference for clearing and the extension responsive to general levels of economic activity both domestic and 12 13 external. The level of domestic trade far outweighed the external trade, activity in general. Timber was a temporary, not a permanent, resource for timber as it did for products and services in general (Condliffe, 1915, and as the opportunities increased for marketing agricultural and pastoral 948). The domestic use of timber was extensive, New Zealand often products, so the amount of land cleared increased and along with it the being referred to as "built of wood" (Roche, 1990, 299). amount of timber available for cutting as an alternative to its being burnt. This temporary increase in supply produced a decrease in price. Wool exports expanded by similar absolute amounts in each of the eighteen seventies, eighties and nineties. Frozen meat exports take off The 1896 Conference on Forestry participants were correct in saying that from the middle of the eighteen eighties and butter and cheese exports too rapid a rate of depletion of the forest was occurring (Bilek & Horgan, expand rapidly in the eighteen nineties (Condliffe, 1915, 901-2). AU of 1990, 2) but they were wrong in attributing it to over-harvesting. Much, this expansion led to clearance for the extension of settlement, peaking in if not most of the cleared timber was never harvested-it was burnt (Roche, the eighteen nineties and led directly to a rising demand for wood as an 1990, 295). It was only economic to mill stands near to markets since the input into several processes associated with such development. Problems amount coming on stream, particularly in the eighteen nineties, was such in the Australian pastoral sector after 1890 probably increased the number as to push the price towards zero if not to reach it. With nearly 14 per of migrant pastoralists coming into New Zealand (Schedvin, 1990, 539) cent of the New Zealand land area being cleared in that decade, a society further adding to the.pressure. of some one million people was not capable of utilising that amount of timber in one gulp. With export quantities actually falling at the start of the nineties, further burning was all but inevitable. The aim of the As more land was made available for clearance for agricultural and process was as rapid a method of clearance as possible, rather than any pastoral production, standing timber prices decreased. Clearance meant form of maximisation of timber production. The details of the process the possibility of a greater stock for the timber industry, provided out of have been outlined elsewhere (Fleet, 1984, 48-50 and 80-1). the natural capital. The process therefore is very different to the situation in a modem afforestation context where obtaining land for planting would mean that there was competition for land use and the production costs for The response of the forestry authorities was to fear an imminent timber timber would rise as other end products prices rose. The process in the famine and to press for a form of bureaucratic intervention. A global nineteenth century New Zealand case, generally accords with the first development of foresters deciding the future needs for planting and stage of the virgin forest resource experience as outlined by Alston (1983, conservation was seen in various countries, including the U.S.A. Australia 6) namely exploitation and mining of the resource. There is little general and New Zealand. The inter-war period therefore saw an interventionist concern with establishing a long-term industry, the timber is essentially response to a situation which might have been avoided, or at least a by-product of, and input into, the pastoral export trade and domestic ameliorated, if subsidies to pastoral activity and institutional demands for 14 15 clearance to foster trade in pastoral products had been absent in the late- low price, if a price was charged at all (A.J.H.R., 1913, lxiii). If the price nineteenth century. Issues of pricing and regulation were only really seen was not zero then it closely approximated to it. as important post 1920. Agricultural output continued to increase at that time with little or no increase in land being made available, through an The reduction of royalties on Kauri at the start of the eighteen nineties by increase in productivity (Philpott & Hussey, 1969, 10). some 20 per cent (A.J.H.R. 1913, 40) was only reversed at the end of the First World War. At first sight such a reduction was folly, merely PART THREE increasing the likelihood of timber being cut and supplied to the market. GOVERNMENT, FOREST OWNERS AND ECONOMIC In terms of massive clearances of land in the eighteen nineties, a RATIONALITY. reduction in royalties seems appropriate, however, if the aim was to ensure as much of the timber as possible was used rather than burnt, since The basic rule which an economist might advocate in a harvesting royalties were imposed on mill output not on the standing timber. decision is that the owner of a mature forest (or of rights to cut in a Destruction involved no payment to the state, whereas processing did. forest) should try and equate the costs of holding onto timber stands with Some general changes in the way in which royalties were charged would the extra returns anticipated to result from doing so. In accordance with have been needed for price changes to be an effective control mechanism the basic idea behind the Hotelling rule, will the interest costs and any in the eighteen nineties. Cruised or appraised volumes of standing timber lease payments be less than the expected change in stumpage value of the was needed in pricing for royalty purposes regardless of whether they standing timber over the review period. If so then stocks should be held. were burnt or processed. This royalty could have been set at some rate If holding costs are equal to, or likely to exceed the addition to stumpage appropriate to compensate for social as well as private costs. Clearly, value then harvestinR appears called for. The decision can be made on a from the tone of Ellis' complaints concerning the failure of royalty rates year to year basis with knowledge required only of current likely changes to keep pace with the rise in retail timber prices in the twenties (Ellis, in log prices, lease costs and interest rate (Sharp & Hull, 1988, 28). 1920, 3), such an approach was a long way from realisation in the eighteen nineties. It appears at first sight that such a decision rule was not really applied in New Zealand in the late-nineteenth century. The scale of clearance was Johnson & Libecap's analysis of the Great Lakes timber position, such that few writers have seen the outcome as anything but wasteful of concludes that unclear property rights, as well as inappropriate pricing led a "valuable" resource. Attempts to consider this question in an economic to over cutting in that case (Johnson & Libecap, 1980, 372). Again framework appear hampered by a lack of price data. The sporadic price changes in government attitudes and regulation would have been required information available is partly literary or subjective in form rather than for any such factors to have worked for conservation in the New Zealand quantified. In an overall sense it was felt, timber was clearly sold at a case. The same authors had earlier argued (Libecap & Johnson, 1979, 16 17 141) that privatisatfon would have assisted correct decision making. embodiment of such an achievement. To avoid a timber shortage the Despite apparent support from Julius Vogel in 1868 when he suggested Forest Service set out on a twin pronged programme of better utilisation small private plots as the way to ensure best management of the resource of the remaining indigenous forest and afforestation, particularly of (N.Z.P.D., 1868, 190-1) the route chosen by government was first to "unproductive" areas such as the Central North Island pumice lands. The subsidise clearance and second, when fear of timber famine struck, to go better utilisation of the indigenous forest was essentially a move towards for direct bureaucratic intervention. greater engineering efficiency - fuller use of the resource and less waste. The afforestation was partly a fad of the time, although in this case not The early twentieth century saw the culmination of the debate. Whereas taken to the extremes of the U.K. Forestry Commission with 60 per cent before this time New Zealanders had generally considered themselves of their plantings being in Scotland, furthest distant from the main overstocked with natural forest areas, by World War One the force of strategic market in South Wales (Geddes, 1922, 51). questioning was becoming far stronger. The assumption that no or little arguments for state forests were similar in the sense that in both countries consideration of the relative returns from timber versus pastoralism was there were proponents arguing essentially that it was essential to move needed, since the latter was clearly superior, could no longer be sustained this way because others were doing so and for reasons of autarky without considerable debate. The timber stock had been reduced to a (Horgan, 1990, 3). point where it had some value. The general Its export price was rising as were domestic retail prices. Instead of allowing such market forces to reign, State afforestation had relatively little impact in terms of output until the however, government chose control by intervention and ownership. nineteen sixties and seventies. By the late twenties state planting was joined by more extensive private afforestation efforts, against bitter In the early twentieth century foresters in New Zealand, as elsewhere, opposition from Ellis on behalf of the Forest Service (Roche, 1987a, 110). appear to have held the view that what was needed in order to conserve One of the government policy aims was to cut back on imports, whilst timber supplies was some form of physical, bureaucratic control. The another was to assist in the expansion of Empire output. The economic unbridled operations of the open market were perceived to have produced basis of many of these decisions were therefore almost secondary to a situation where only interventionism could save the forest. As one political and other motives. Symptomatic of the economic miscalculation writer put it "the destruction of the forests of New Zealand forms a was the enthusiastic appraisal of the prospects for the future of New lamentable history." (Daly, 1924, 177). Zealand forestry given in 1925 by E.P.Neale. He was over-optimistic on many fronts, not least in the assessment that competition from Australia Shortly after World War 1 the process of interventionist bureaucratic in producing pines was unlikely to eventuate, except for Tasmania. He control had been accomplished in many parts of the Empire. The also asserted that: "The well-watered strip of Southern Chile is so narrow establishment of the New Zealand Forest Service in 1919 represents the as to be almost negligible as a source of timber supply" (Neale, 1925, 19 18 322), a not well founded assertion in the light of Chile's emergence as a 1990, 8). The precautionary value of diversity (Pearce, Barbier & major source of such timber in recent times. Markandya, 1990, 15-16), was subsequently shown in the economic effects of loss due to fungal disease. The outcome of the inter-war The thrust of legislation and intervention in the inter-war period was decisions have been that almost 90 per cent of current exotic plantations moving away from a free market position. Quantitative restrictions on are now composed of Pinus Radiata and some 96 per cent of wood fibre exports were implemented until revoked in 1928 in the face of pressure produced in New Zealand comes from the exotic plantations. Putting all from rising unemployment. Some raising in royalty levels did occur, but ones eggs in this particular basket is a risky economic and biological the main aim seems to have been associated with securing long term game. supplies for the local market and cutting back import growth. At the the rate of forest clearance before 1914, but may have helped encourage same time domestic retail processed timber prices were regulated in an the stock purchase attempts of companies such as the Kauri Timber attempt to keep them below export levels, to secure short term supplies Company which were substantially frustrated by regulation, as well by for the local market (Roche, 1987b, 196). Imports faced successively their inability to control the market. Post 1920 the emphasis appears to raised tariff barriers in 1927, 1930 and 1932 (Roche, 1987b, 199). have been placed predominantly upon direct control and ownership with A free market situation would probably not have greatly slowed unfettered market prices playing only a small part in the process. With the major clearance programme complete at the start of the inter-war period, there was a chance to e·stablish a privately-owned, sustainable forest industry. Intervention was predicated on the assumption that the state, rather than private enterprise, was the appropriate body to undertake such a task. The major part of the nation's forests were already in state hands, but little attempt had been made at afforestation or production forestry before 1920. The appeal of rapidly growing exotic trees resulted in a virtual mono-culture. If as Ellis felt, the state could incorporate the social values of the forest better than the private sector, then a relatively poor job was done in terms of risk minimisation by spreading the production amongst a diverse stock of trees. Horgan has described the afforestation result of this concentration upon Pinus Radiata amongst both the public and private afforestation campaigns as turning that tree into "a sort of battery hen of the plant world" (Horgan, 20 21 PART FOUR can be compared to the rate of depletion in New Zealand's peak period THE AMAZON: A CASE OF REPETITION ? of conversion of forest to farmland, the late-nineteenth century, which saw the clearance of some 22.5 per cent of the 1840 forested area (estimated The causes of deforestation outlined in the New Zealand pre-1914 case from Condliffe, 1959, 134-5) between 1890 and 1900. were essentially related to a clearance for agriculture imperative. The expansion of an internal market-based economy for a wide range of products impacted on the forest area in a negative manner and this effect A dramatic and similar process to that observable in the New Zealand was significantly enhanced by the demands of the international economy. case, is to be found on the frontier regions of the Amazonian basin. New Zealand was increasingly brought into the international market-place, Timber cutting is only partially responsible along with agricultural principally by virtue of the price incentives for wool production and other clearance and fires (McNeill, 1988, 18-19). exports and latterly by the technological changes associated with transport achieved by burning rather than clear felling for milling. Cattle ranching, improvements and refrigeration techniques which respectively reduced general development and settlement are the underlying driving forces, costs and opened up new possibilities for markets. New Zealand timber often spurred by government subsidy and at times by speculative activity was at this stage a by-product of clearance. Other places such as (Hecht, 1985, 663). The result is that forest resources are plunged onto Tasmania are said to have suffered in much the same manner (Dargavel, the market in much the same way as they were in the late-nineteenth 1988, 191 and 197), although the extent of clearance by fire alone appears century New Zealand case. Attempts to raise the level of royalties would to have been somewhat less. The history of major clearances such as that therefore be met by an increase in the burning off, unless those royalties of the United States (Williams, 1982) give the impression that change was are levied on the existing timber stands and can be enforced. Imposing slower and much of the timber was utilised in one form or another. royalties on timber output only distorts the picture in favour of Clearance is principally destruction. At the margin or frontier of Amazonian expansion the rate of Whereas little economic explanation of this phenomenon of a rapid clearance and the subsequent level of timber supply is such that there may extension and intrusion of a market-based economy has been attempted be no price millers are willing to pay. Regulatory enforcement of royalty in an historical sense a very similar case has been presented for the payments in such circumstances implies that the rate of clearance should present day situation in the Amazonian rain forest. The amount of timber be slowed, in contrast to the subsidy approach which suggests a more utilised from the cleared area is but a small part of the total available. It rapid rate is desirable. is agricultural clearance that is primarily responsible for the disappearance of the forest cover. The rate of depletion is currently estimated at 11 per The process of development in the Amazon, has been extensively cent of the total forest area in the decade 1975 to 1985, with little being documented in several case studies. A typical process is one occurring cleared before 1975 (Pearce, Barbier & Markandya, 1990, 192-3). This in two stages. Initially transport links and settlements are established, 22 23 together with the expansion of cattle ranching which forms the basis of voiced even by contemporaries (Gisborne, 1888, 233-4) as well as essentially speculative claims to property rights over the land. Next the complaints of selected logging by species and by value. more extensive clearing occurs within the newly settled area once the Kahikatea formed the bulk of the exported timbers, with Kauri being the claims are legitimised. (Summarized in Pearce, Barbier & Markandya, major component (Jackson, 1990, 4-5). The best trees only were taken 1990, 197). and imposing royalties on output alone, as is the case in both instances Government assistance occurs not only in the form of legitimisation of claims to property rights, but in direct subsidisation and Kauri and under examination, only seems to enhance this effect. encouragement of the clearance process. (Hall, 1986, 412). Population growth and easier transport access are seen as contributing to a major The underlying rationale is one which sees agricultural products as clearly discontinuity in development (Feamside, 1986, 1). the preferred use for land. A freely operating market may well say much the same thing, although with subsidies removed it is less likely to say it With the full social costs of forest depletion taken into The terms under which rights to land are granted often include so strongly. requirements for land to be cleared within a specified period, frustrating account the strength of the deforestation case is weakened. The historical any attempt, if the owners so wished, at moving towards an optimal rate and current examinations of the impact of clearing virgin forest for of depletion by restricting supply and in so doing raising prices to a true agricultural expansion to meet a rapidly growing internal and external market level. market, find the process wanting in some respects. In current circumstances, existing timber prices are pushed below a true Temporal and geographical distance clearly do not guarantee a difference market rate by subsidies both paid directly to ranchers and indirectly in approach. New Zealand in the nineteenth century and the modern through payment for such things as roading improvements. Far from experience in the Amazon can be added to Richard G. Lillard's 1984 list taxing ranchers and small farmers to compensate for the loss of other of examples of a common theme of: forest products, soil erosion and climatic change amongst a wider list " ... chaotic, unplanned, heedless cutting on eighteenth century (Pearce, Barbier & Markandya, 1990, 199), Government appears intent on Japanese Islands,on the Western Himalayas in the nineteenth subsidising their activities, thus further distorting market signals. century, and during the present century in Papua New Guinea, Tasmania, Ghana and other African Nations." (Lillard, 1984, xvi). To talk as the studies do, of waste, of logging as a by-product of agricultural clearance and of selective clearance of only a few select tree Lillard's findings came from discussion on the experience of all those species, such as Mahogany and of then only bringing the best out of the cases in a 1983 Conference. Essentially the underlying message is pretty forest is more than reminiscent of the New Zealand nineteenth century clear to those who care to discern it. An over rapid rate of destruction is experience. perceived, although how you determine over rapidity is something of a The same descriptions of waste are found to have been 24 25 moot point. Globally in the recent past the actual rate of diminution of The uncertainty of future environmental effects are such as to render the the forest reserve has been somewhat slower than many might lead one quick-fix appeal of solutions such as those proposed by Libecap and to believe. For the twenty years ending in 1985 the decline in the world's Johnson far more difficult to implement successfully than would appear forest and woodlands was less than 5 per cent of the total (Kula, 1988, at first sight. Such efforts have more to do with current, narrow allocative 63). Such a percentage is still a significant decline and the effects are efficiency arguments than long run sustainability and any accounting for ' magnified if quality deterioration accompanied that decline. Where externalities visited upon the environment and the future. The message selective logging of particular species occurs, the more mature and better of Libecap and Johnson, however, can be taken as demonstrating that trees are extracted, accompanied by some destruction in their removal. intervention without foresight can make things worse and has certainly The result is to reduce the value of the timber left on land which remains done so in both late- nineteenth century New Zealand and in the apparently still covered in trees. Amazonian case. Since World War Two a greater emphasis has also been placed upon deforestation in tropical areas than was previously the case. The typical process in places such as Indonesia, Papua New Guinea and .elsewhere has involved the extension of these forests more completely into the international economy, with logging company practices attracting much adverse comment. The thrust of policy and practice has been the maximisation of timber production (Gillis, 1988, 51, Hurst, 1990, 142-5). Whatever the methods chosen to counter-act undesirable features of deforestation, whether the market is left to operate or the extension of regulation and state intervention occurs is largely a matter for individual value judgements. The urging of caution is warranted, however, since the risks are high and the future uncertain. Under the precautionary principles currently being developed in environmental economics literature some resources would be required to be set aside now, to compensate for disastrous worst-case scenario outcomes for future generations (see Perrings, 1990). This was not done in the eighteenth and nineteenth century cases and appears unlikely to be so in the twentieth. 27 26 nineteenth century forest case the motivation came from a combination of CONCLUSIONS inappropriate policies and the enhanced attractiveness of good returns The future remains uncertain, but moving towards more rapid destruction from pastoral products compared to indigenous timber stands. Part of this by subsidising clearance activity at the expense of the forest is not only attractive rate of return was based on the fertility of newly cleared lands. counter to allocative efficiency criteria, but over-rides the precautionary At the same time the flood of timber stands thrown onto the market' principle and assumes little responsibility for future generations' welfare. depressed their value, confirming the perception that farming was the best The extent to which past or present generations bear responsibility for the land use choice. In the longer term therefore the indigenous forest capital future consequences of their actions is a matter of debate, but intrinsically stock was depleted (degraded) for short term gains. Rational economic it is no less important a matter than is the question of intra-generational forces may well have set off the process but political rhetoric and equity. economic myopia assured its rapid continuation, probably past any appropriate cross-over position. Deforestation and agricultural expansion resulted from growing international trade pressures in nineteenth century New Zealand. The point in time at which a possible trade-off was reached in New Technological changes opened new markets through reducing transport Zealand would appear to lie in the early part of the twentieth century. costs and introducing refrigeration. This represented a shock to the The true price of timber was disguised rather than revealed by subsidies system, given its rapidity, which the system responded to in dramatic and other interventions and over rapid depletion was the result. Social or New Zealand possessed a large area of forest relative to its environmental costs were not given serious consideration before 1920. In more densely The timber industry expanded somewhat haphazardly as the result of a settled areas such as Europe, the history of deforestation had been a mining or quarrying operation of the area being cleared. Whilst export relatively long drawn out process, with timber always occupying an logging may have deleteriously affected one particular species, Kauri, in important part in the rural economy. Societies faced with a more rapid general it was not the external logging trade that was the root cause of adjustment process appear to over-emphasise the need for a rapid rate of deforestation in New Zealand, any more than is currently the case in depletion. They fail to set an appropriate level of royalties and in fact Amazonia. subsidise the destruction process. environmental and economic costs, imposed on standing timber whether fashion. population size and dramatic change was possible. An appropriate level of royalty payments to cover both for clearance or for use as an input, may be an alternative to state The implications of the way in which adjustment was achieved may ownership. In colonial New Zealand the real problem was that neither include short term gains at the expense of long term degradation was tried, subsidised clearance was the chosen path. problems. Amazon seems set to repeat the dose. Currently some have attributed some cases of resource degradation to poverty (see Perrings, 1989). In the New Zealand The Brazilian QUANTITY (miliion sup. ft.) - 1 oo VALUE (£ '000), I 000 ,...:.. °' N00 °' °' N -"" ("<) I -- V'l 00 JI I GO I- !'\/ ..,; v II \ JI' + -I 700 11 -[GOO 00 [i3 °' "Cf ~ d.lti:: t-< Jl.. 0 N °' 0 IZl §, f5 ~ t-< 'O I /\ 1 0 1 I _ • \/I -I 400 40 ·- 20 ·- ::::i r..i ~ .:r • .T B ~ < ::i:: -I 500 I \I/II-;, . I I 80 ~ t-< x t I 80 +· /I 1 GO I_ 0. 80 u ii.i u u ..... ::::i 0 1 1 IJ " G G 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 G 7 0 1 0 7 1 0 0 ·a G 1 0 0 0 0 G 0 1 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 G 1 0 G 0 IZl G 1 1 0 2 0 2 0 1 0 J 0 G 1 0 J G 1 0 J 0 YEAR I~QUANTITY -l-VALUE I IZl t-< ~ PARTICULAR EXPORTS AS A PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL EXPORTS 0 t:l.. ><:1 90 ....:i 80 ~ < ,...:.. ~ \0 u "" N ~ ..,; ~ 60 °' 50 "Cf d.l 40 t:l.. Jl.. 0 00 N 00 ~ ~ < ::i:: 0 IZl ~ gJ ~u - s ::i:: u ""'. Iii 70 ., , ~/ ,--• 11111 ~ ~ / 20 . ------~ ~ x.,,, ~· ,., 30 0 ~ .._, ii.i u ,,.. 11111 10 ..... ::::i 0 IZl 0 1848 1853 1858 1863 1868 1873 llll Minerals 1878 0 Forestry 1883 1888 +·Pastoral 1893 1898 <> Agricultural 1903 1908 1913 1918 31 30 CHART 3: ROYALTIES ON SAWN TIMBER 1885-1920 BIBLIOGRAPHY Source: (A.J.H.R. 1913, 40). Adami, (1918), Final Report of the Reconstruction Committee of the Forestry Sub-Committee, [Cd 8881] British Parliamentary Papers 1917-18, XVII, p.423. (/) 0 c 0 <D 0 "' "'"' (/) I [\ F ~~~L____J__ _ _I ~ OllO • IJHIIOJ-" A.J.H.R., (1913), Appendix to the Journals Representatives, Vol. 2, cl. 2 Wellington. of the House of Alston, R.M. (1983), The Individual Versus the Public Interest, Boulder, co. Arnold, R. (1976), "The Virgin Forest Harvest and the Development of Colonial New Zealand", New Zealand Geographer, Vol. 32, pp.105-26 Beasley, M. (1930), "The Timber Industry of New Zealand", M.A. Thesis University of Auckland. Bilek E.M. & G.P.Horgan, (1990), "Organisational and Administrative Challenges Involving Large Scale Transfer of Public Assets to the Private Sector: New Zealand's Experience", Paper to: XIXth World Congress, International Union of Forest Research Organisations, Montreal, August, 1990. -< 111 )> Bloomfield G.T. (1984), New Zealand: A Handbook of Historical Statistics, Boston, MASS. JJ (/) Ot0 • LMO:HD-" Carter, B. (1972), "The Kauri Timber Company 1888-1914", M.A. Thesis University of Melbourne. ON• -.J_.IO_. Condliffe, J.B. (1915), "The External Trade of New Zealand," New Zealand Official Yearbook, pp.858-962. Wellington. Condliffe, J.B. (1959), New Zealand in the Making, 2nd.ed. London. Conway, M.J. (1974), "Indigenous Forest Policy: Past and Future", in Forestry Development Conference Papers, Wellington. Daly, S.J. ed. (1924), Timber and Timber Products, London. Dargavel, J. (1988), "Changing Capital Structure, the State and Tasmanian Forestry", in World Deforestation in the Twentieth Century, J.F.Richards 32 33 and RP.Tucker, eds. Durham NC. pp.189-210. Ellis, L.M. (1920), Forest Conditions in New Zealand, Wellington. Libecap, G.D. & RN.Johnson (1979), "Property Rights, Nineteenth Century Federal Timber Policy, and the Conservation Movement," Journal of Economic History, Vol.XXXIX No.I. March. pp.129-142. Fearnside, P.M. (1986), Human Carrving Capacity of the Brazilian Rainforest, N.Y. Lillard, RG. (1984), "Impressions of Session 2", in History of SustainedYield Forestry: A Symposium, H.K.Steen Gen.ed. Santa Cruz CA. Fleet, K.H. (1984), New Zealand's Forests, Auckland. McNeill, J.R. (1988), "Deforestation in the Auracaria Zone of Southern Brazil, 1900-1983", in World Deforestation in the Twentieth Century, J.F.Richards and RP.Tucker, eds. Durham NC. pp.15-32. Geddes Committee, (1920), Second Interim Report of the Committee on National Expenditure, .[Cd.1582] London. Neale, E.P. (1925), "Economics Notes", The Accountants Journal, April 20, pp.319-324. Gillis, M. (1988), "Indonesia: Public Policies, Resource Management and the Tropical Forest", in Public Policies and the Misuse of Forest Resources, R Repetto and M. Gillis, eds. Cambridge. pp.43-113. N.Z.O.Y.B. (1914), New Zealand Official Yearbook, Wellington. Gisbome, W. (1988), The Colony of New Zealand, London. N.Z.P.D. (1868), New Zealand Parliamentary Debates, Wellington. Hall, A.L. (1986), "More of the Same in Brazilian Amazonia: A Comment on Fearnside", World Development, Vol.14, pp.411-414. Pearce, D.W., E.B.Barbier & A. Markandya (1990), Sustainable Development, Aldershot. Hecht, S.B. (1985), "Environment Development and Politics: Capital Accumulation and the Livestock Sector in Eastern Amazonia", World Development, Vol. 13, No. 6, pp.663-684. Perrings, C.A. (1989), "An Optimal Path to Extinction ? Poverty and Resource Degradation in the Open Agrarian Economy," Journal of Development Economics, Vol.30 pp.1-24. Horgan, G.P. (1990), "The Economic Impact of Forest Policies". Paper to the "Trees for Survival Conference", Auckland University, June, 1990. Perrings, C.A. (1990), "'Reserved Rationality' and the 'Precautionary Principle': Technological Change, Time and Uncertainty in Environmental Decision-Making", Auckland University Working Papers in Economics, No.79. Hurst, P. (1990), Rainforest Politics, London. Jackson, K.E. (1990), "Of Trees, Trade and Clearance: When Kauri was King", University of Auckland Working Papers, No.69. Johnson, R.N. & G.D. Libecap, (1980), "Efficient Markets and Great Lakes Timber: A Conservation Issue Re-examined", Explorations in Economic History, Vol.17, No.4. Oct. pp.372-385. Kirkland, A. & LG. Trotman, (1974), "Historical Outlines oflndigenous Forest Legislation and Policy for State Forests," Forestrv Development Conference Papers. Kula, E. (1988), The Economics of Forestry: Modern Theory and Practice, London. ' Philpott, B.P. & D.D. Hussey (1969), "Productivity and Income of New Zealand Agriculture 1921-67", Lincoln College Agricultural Economics Research Unit: Research Report, No. 59. Roche, M.M. (1987 a), "Company Afforestation: Patterns and Processes During the 'First Planting Boom"', Proceedings, Thirteenth New Zealand Geography Conference, pp.107-111, Hamilton. Roche, M.M. (1987 b), "New Zealand Timber for the New Zealanders: Regulatory Controls and the Dislocation of the Pacific Rim Timber Trade in the 1920's and 1930's", Proceedings, Fourteenth New Zealand Geography Conference and Fifty Sixth ANZAAS Congress - Geographical Sciences, pp.195-203, Palmerston North. Roche, M.M. (1990), "The New Zealand Timber Economy, 1840-1935", Journal of Historical Geography, Vol.16, pp.295-313. Schedvin, C.B. (1990), "Staples and Regions of Pax Britannica", Economic History Review, Vol. XLII, No. 4, pp.533-559. Searle, G. (1975), Rush to Destruction, Wellington. Sharp, B.M.H. & B.ff.Hull (1988), "Forest Economics and Policy", New Zealand Forestry, Feb. pp.25-29. Simkin, C.G.F. (1951), The Instability of a Dependent Economy, Oxford. Stobart, T.J. (1927), Timber Trade of the United Kingdom, Vol.I, London. Stone, R.C.J. (1973), Makers of Fortune: A Colonial Business Community and its Fall, Auckland. Williams, M. (1982), "Clearing the United States Forests: Pivotal Years 1810-1860", Journal of Historical Geography, Vol. 8, No. 1, pp.12-28. UNIVERSITY OFI W.A. ! LIBRA.RY ! a---~~·==l 111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111 A10473084B