Democratisation in Indonesia: From Transition to
Transcription
Democratisation in Indonesia: From Transition to
Institutions, Economic Recovery, and Macroeconomic Vulnerability in Indonesia and Malaysia Thomas Pepinsky Department of Political Science Yale University P.O. Box 208301 New Haven, CT 06511 [email protected] This version: July 17, 2006 8844 words (including notes) Prepared for the workshop East Asia Ten Years After the Crisis The Australian National University, Canberra July 21-22, 2006 DRAFT: Comments welcome! Please do not cite without permission Institutions, Economic Recovery, and Macroeconomic Vulnerability in Indonesia and Malaysia 1. Introduction In Indonesia and Malaysia, the Asian Financial Crisis was as much a political crisis as an economic one. Policies adopted by the respective governments had fostered over a decade of strong economic growth, but this growth came with structural weaknesses that left each country vulnerable to the vagaries of investor confidence and cross-border capital movements. These weaknesses arose from each country’s political economy: in each country an autocratic government used economic policy and political favoritism to reward its supporters with little regard for their potential downstream costs. The Asian Financial Crisis led each country to take extraordinary adjustment measures, and ignited distributional conflicts that ultimately drove Soeharto from power and severely tested the ruling coalition in Malaysia. Subsequently, the years since the crisis have seen political contests in each country over the implementation of reforms designed to foster economic recovery. This chapter shows how politics has defined the course of economic recovery in Indonesia and Malaysia. Malaysia’s economic recovery began earlier and remained more robust than other countries in the region as a result of the country’s adoption of selective capital controls and an exchange rate peg together with expansionary macroeconomic policy. But Malaysia’s successful stabilization package meant that the government could escape the tough economic reforms that would promote more healthy long-term growth. Most of the same structural weaknesses that made the country vulnerable to the Asian Financial Crisis persist in Malaysia today, even after the retirement of former Prime Minister Mahathir Mohamad. These include extensive political intervention in the economy, as well as corruption and inefficiency in government owned or politically favored firms. By contrast, the fall of Soeharto and Indonesia’s subsequent democratization, along with IMF mandated stabilization measures and institutional reforms, have not have the much hoped for effect of promoting rapid economic recovery. In particular, Indonesia’s decentralization program has increased opportunities for local corruption, and the implementation of economic reforms has been hamstrung by political instability and corruption at the national level. Only under President Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono, elected in October 2004, have reform measures began to show fruit. The experiences of Indonesia and Malaysia suggest several insights for the political economy of economic reform. Far-ranging political transitions, as took place in Indonesia, can lead to delays in economic recovery due to the extensive transactions costs associated with institutional re-equilibration—the process whereby economic and political actors adjust to new institutional rules. Democratic transitions and fiscal decentralization, and competition over the ability to define new institutional rules, can yield new opportunities for rent-seeking. The product of these reforms in Indonesia has been a complex regulatory regime coupled with weak legal enforcement. While normatively desirable, democratization and fiscal decentralization have not overcome the fundamental problem of weak institutions that hinder economic growth. Political continuity, as in Malaysia, minimizes the transactions costs associated with institutional re-equilibration. The political tradeoff is that economic recovery masks the need for economic reform, and obscures the same macroeconomic vulnerabilities that earlier led to a severe economic crisis. The focus on institutions here does not deny the importance of other influences on the course of economic recovery in the two countries. Indonesia’s crisis was far worse than Malaysia’s crisis, in part due to the almost total breakdown of Indonesia’s economic and political institutions in 1998. This means that Indonesia had further to go to achieve economic recovery than Malaysia did. Political changes in Indonesia also extended far beyond legal and institutional reform: in the provinces of East Timor, Aceh, and West Papua, secessionist movements have threatened the very integrity of the Indonesian state. Sectarian violence in Maluku and Kalimantan brought simmering social conflicts to light, and the Indonesian military has sought contain the new threat of Jemaah Islamiyah while reevaluating its own role in Indonesian politics. Malaysia has had none of these problems. Corruption, too, has always been more extensive in Indonesia than in Malaysia. Yet there is still much to learn from these two countries. Focusing on the (often informal) institutional bases of each country’s economy helps us to understand the mechanisms through which growth occurs and macroeconomic vulnerabilities develop. On this count, the comparison between institutional change and continuity in Indonesia and Malaysia reveals important themes in East Asia’s recovery. 2. Economic Crisis and Recovery Malaysia’s economic contraction was shallower, and its subsequent growth more robust, than Indonesia’s. A common misperception among many regional specialists is that Malaysia’s crisis was less severe than Indonesia’s because Indonesia was ex ante more vulnerable. Indonesia did face a more severe problem of imprudent lending than Malaysia, manifest in a burden of non-performing loans exceeding by some estimates 40% of all loans in Indonesia compared to around 20% in Malaysia.1 But Malaysian development financing was concentrated in the stock market rather than in bank lending: Malaysia’s stock market capitalization exceeded 227% of GDP in 1995, compared to just 19% in Indonesia (cited in Jomo and Hamilton-Hart 1 J.P. Morgan estimated that at the height of the crisis, between 30 and 35 percent of all loans in Indonesia were nonperforming. In Malaysia, the figure was 15 to 25 percent. Similar figures for Standard and Poor’s are 40 percent for Indonesia and 20 percent for Malaysia (cited in Berg 1999: 8). 2001: 81). Between its peak on June 8, 1997 and its trough on September 21, 1998, the Jakarta Stock Exchange Composite Index shrank by 65.3%, from 741.8 to 256.8—a severe turnaround by any reckoning. But the Kuala Lumpur Stock Exchange (KLSE) Composite Index, between February 21, 1997 and September 1, 1998, shrank by 79.3% from 1271.6 to just 262.7. For Malaysia’s political economy, dominated by the stock market for the distribution of patronage in addition to the financing of big-ticket development projects, this was a disastrous turnaround. In fact, the ultimate severity of the economic shock in each country was endogenous to the policies that their regimes adopted in combating the crisis. A comparison of growth rates during the crisis illustrates economic contraction and subsequent recovery, demonstrating the economic consequences of political events in each country (Figure 1). 25 20 15 10 5 Indonesia 0 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 Q1 Q3 -5 Q1 1996 1996 1997 1997 1998 1998 1999 1999 2000 2000 2001 2001 -10 Malaysia -15 -20 -25 Figure 1: Quarterly Real Growth Rates, 1996-2001 (Annualized, Seasonally Adjusted) Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics The data show in that economic contraction actually began earlier in Malaysia than in Indonesia, with negative growth rates first recorded in the first quarter of 1998. As currency and stock speculators attacked Malaysia, anti-Western outbursts by Mahathir and increasing tensions between Mahathir and Deputy Prime Minister and Finance Minister Anwar Ibrahim contributed further to the country’s economic downturn. But in September 1998, Malaysia embarked on its controversial adjustment strategy of macroeconomic expansion made feasible by capital controls with a fixed ringgit exchange rate—and Mahathir sacked his deputy. Despite this political shake-up, Malaysia’s economic quickly stabilized, and had turned around by mid-1999. In Indonesia, by contrast, while growth slowed abruptly in late 1997, growth did not trend negative until the third quarter of 1998, following Soeharto’s resignation on May 21, 1998. But in the wake of Soeharto’s resignation, the Indonesia economy contracted severely, enough that Indonesia registered a stunning fourteen percent economic contraction in 1998. After bottoming out in the first quarter of 1999, the Indonesian economy rebounded to register positive seasonal growth of just under two percent in the fourth quarter of that year. Malaysia’s comparatively rapid economic recovery despite its radical departure from IMF orthodoxy of financial openness and macroeconomic discipline sparked some debate about the causal role of Malaysia’s adjustment policies in spurring economic recovery. At the very least, Malaysia’s policies do not seem to have done much harm. Even Paul Krugman, who suggested in August 1998 a policy basket similar to Malaysia’s, has been circumspect in attributing economic recovery to Malaysia’s policies rather than a secular improvement in investment climate (Krugman 1999). There are reasons enough to believe that the correlation between capital controls and the onset of economic recovery is misleading. Economic crises never last forever, and after three quarters of negative GDP growth, Malaysia may have simply bottomed out. Evidence in favor of this conclusion comes from the fact that South Korea and Thailand began to recover about the time that Malaysia began to recover. Alternatively, Malaysia might have recovered still faster had it not imposed capital controls. To assess the counterfactual that Malaysia would have recovered even without capital controls and a ringgit peg, Kaplan and Rodrik (2001) compared a number of economic indicators in Malaysia with other indicators in South Korea, Indonesia, and Thailand, taking into account that the other countries adopted IMF policies long before September 1998, while Malaysia’s economy was still deteriorating at that time. They find strong support that capital controls in Malaysia were associated with a smaller drop in GDP growth, industrial output, and real wages than the IMF programs in other crisis countries. Since 1999, the year by which the crisis in each country had finally abated, both countries’ economies have grown steadily, although at lower rates than they enjoyed before the crisis (Figure 2). 20000 16000 12000 Indonesia Malaysia 8000 4000 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 0 Figure 2: Real Per Capita GDP, 1990-2005 Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics In Indonesia, per capita real GDP grew by an average of 5.66% between 1991 and 1996, but this has slowed to 3.05% between 1999 and 2005. In Malaysia, the same figures are 6.72% between 1991 and 1996 and 3.49% between 1999 and 2005. Malaysian GDP did contract in 2001 due to a slump in global demand for Malaysian electronic exports coinciding with a global economic slowdown (see Martinez 2002). But the trends over time are clear: the economic crisis represents a clear break in each country between a period of rapid economic growth amidst relatively stable politics and a period of more modest economic growth. 3. Indonesia: Institutional Change and Macroeconomic Vulnerability Indonesia’s severe economic contraction drove Soeharto from power, spelling the end of the New Order regime over which he had ruled for thirty-two years. Soeharto’s hand-picked successor, B.J. Habibie, was singularly unable to contain Indonesia’s reformasi movement, and in 1999 lost Indonesia’s first democratic election since the 1950s to the liberal Muslim politician Abdurrahman Wahid (Gus Dur) of the National Awakening Party. Gus Dur, however, served erratically, alienating pro-democracy activists and allied political parties alike while mismanaging Indonesia’s economic recovery and using his position to amass financial resources through the state’s logistical monopoly Bulog (Liddle 2001; Malley 2002). He himself succumbed to a corruption scandal in 2001, succeeded by his Vice President, Megawati Sukarnoputri of the Indonesian Democratic Party of Struggle (PDI-P). In contesting the first direct presidential election in 2004, Megawati lost to her former Coordinating Minister for Politics and Security, General Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono, usually known by his initials SBY. This total of five Presidents within the space of just eight years is an important indicator of the political changes ushered in by Indonesia’s economic crisis. Presidential turnover notwithstanding, a persistent concern for Indonesia is the penetration of the Indonesian government by wealthy pribumi (“indigenous,” i.e. non-Chinese Indonesian) business figures. SBY’s Vice President is Jusuf Kalla, who had a long career as head of the influential conglomerate NV Hadji Kalla while rising in the ranks of the dominant party Golkar during the New Order. His brother, Achmad Kalla, currently heads PT Bukaka Teknik Utama, a multinational firm with diversified construction investments of which Jusuf was a commissioner until 2001. Under SBY, Bukaka and Hadji Kalla have won a number of important concessions from central and regional governments. SBY’s wife Kristiani Herawati is the daughter of the late General Sarwo Edhie Wibowo, who was instrumental in the massacre of students and leftists during Soeharto’s rise to power in 1965. Many believe that she has business connections owing to her strong family ties to the military, and efforts to extricate the Indonesian military from the corporate world have been halting. 2 Besides Jusuf Kalla, other members of SBY’s United Indonesia Cabinet have clear links with the Indonesian business community, including the Coordinating Minister for People’s Welfare and former Coordinating Minister of the Economy Aburizal Bakrie, whose family controls the influential Bakrie Group, and Minister for National Planning Paskah Suzetta, whose business interests have included property and investment. The Bakrie Group openly collaborates with the National Planning Board (Bappenas) to develop its land holdings, and Aburizal’s wealth has grown substantially since he joined SBY’s government.3 Foreign economic observers agree that business interests such as these have hindered the course of Indonesian trade policy reform.4 Government trading monopolies and government-owned enterprises still exist in many sectors; these firms are reported to be rife with corruption, and privatization drives yield speculation of corruption and favoritism.5 Indonesia’s central bank is now formally independent from the executive and legislature, but reports of interference by Kalla and others in the Bank’s monetary policy decisions are common.6 2 Wisnu Dewabrata, “Berbisnis dengan bendera Markas Besar TNI ,” Kompas, February 8, 2006; “Definisi bisnis militer belum jelas,” Kompas, March 4, 2006; interview with Hery Trianto, Reporter for Bisnis Indonesia, March 2, 2006. 3 “Kekayaan Aburizal meningkat,” Kompas, May 24, 2006. 4 Several interviews with officials at international development agencies in Jakarta, February-March 2006. 5 “‘Black hole-nya di situ [perdagangan]...’,” Bisnis Indonesia, February 15, 2006; “Privatisasi diminta dihentikan sementara,” Bisnis Indonesia, March 31, 2006. 6 Interview with an economist at a foreign economic institution, February 2006. The news is not all bad, as other economic ministers in SBY’s Cabinet, notably the current Coordinating Minister for the Economy Boediono, Minister of Finance Sri Mulyani Indrawati, and Minister of Trade Mari Elke Pangestu, have reputations as technocrats rather than business figures. The technocrats have directed several contentious but much-needed policy reforms, including fuel subsidy cuts of October 2005 that were unpopular among many lower class Indonesians. Yet the bifurcation of SBY’s Cabinet between technocrats and wellconnected entrepreneurs recalls the policy divide under Soeharto between technocrats, and socalled “financial generals” and nationalists (see Crouch 1978; Liddle 1991: 29-32; Mackie and MacIntyre 1994: 35-37). Based on the presence of so many members of the New Order establishment in post-New Order governments, some have suggested that Indonesia has developed a ruling oligarchy that has weathered a difficult institutional transition without actually losing its power (see e.g. Robison and Hadiz 2004). This is probably an exaggeration. Even though many members of the New Order elite have survived the transition to democracy, the rules of the game have changed in important ways. The change from dictatorship to democracy on a national scale is only the beginning. In 2001, Indonesia embarked on a radical policy of decentralization that dismantled many of the institutions of centralized political rule under the New Order. Constitutional amendments in 2004 reinforced this move towards regional autonomy (otonomi daerah). Not only are national elections democratic, so are provincial and local elections. With decentralization has come a new phenomenon of regional splitting (pemekaran daerah, or “the blossoming of areas”), referring to the subdivision of existing subnational political units into new ones. Since 1998, seven new provinces have been created: North Maluku, formerly part of Maluku, in 1999; Bangka-Belitung, formerly part of South Sumatra, in 2000; Banten, formerly part of West Java, also in 2000; Gorontalo, formerly part of North Sulawesi, also in 2000; West Irian Jaya (Irian Jaya Barat), formerly part of Papua, in 2003; Riau Islands (Kepulauan Riau), formerly part of Riau, in 2004, and West Sulawesi (Sulawesi Barat), formerly part of South Sulawesi, also in 2004. With the loss of East Timor, this has raised the number of Indonesian provinces from 27 in 1998 to 33 today. Other new provinces have been proposed as well, including a province of Central Irian Jaya, a province of East Sulawesi, and several subdivisions of Aceh (Nanggroe Aceh Darussalam). At the sub-provincial level, over a hundred new regencies (kabupaten) and cities (kota) have been created. Political decentralization—in particular, fiscal decentralization—has a clear economic logic. It removes the central government’s monopoly over the creation of many important facets of economic policy, inducing subnational political units to compete with one another to attract investment (see e.g. Tiebout 1956; Weingast 1995). For example, provinces that eliminate inefficient labor regulations will attract more investment; and this will encourage other provinces to emulate them. Combined with local level democracy, this gives citizens a powerful tool to enhance government responsiveness and spur local economic development. Even if provincial administrations do not respond to logic of inter-jurisdictional competition, instead using their positions to generate personal profit or to protect vested interests, with democratic elections their constituents will punish them for corruption and poor governance by voting them out of office. In Indonesia, several studies have found that local level corruption has decreased since decentralization in 2001 (Henderson and Kuncoro 2004, 2006). This is consistent with crossnational evidence, which finds a negative relationship between decentralization and corruption at the national level (see e.g. Fisman and Gatti 2002). But many Indonesian political observers have found a perverse logic to decentralization and regional splitting. Instead of fostering inter-jurisdictional competition, decentralization and regional splitting have increased the opportunities for local corruption by expanding the number of independent veto points and government agencies across the country.7 Without the heavy hand of Soeharto in the background, these agencies are now even more willing to extort bribes and levies. Local elites interested in securing regular funding from the central government can create what amount to personal fiefdoms in new sub-provincial jurisdictions. The logic is similar to that of Shleifer and Vishny (1993), who suggest two different institutional equilibria that support corruption. In one, a strong central government has an incentive to maximize its total take in bribes from an economy, and hence punishes its lower level representatives in the regions if they levy bribes to an extent that they discourage growth and investment. Such an institutional structure leads to a high total number of bribes taken, but a relatively small average bribe, and New Order Indonesia matched this model well (see MacIntyre 2000, 2003). An alternative institutional structure has no central apparatus that can coordinate bribery and corruption among bureaucrats or government agencies throughout a country. The lack of coordination among bribe takers implies that the total amount of bribery may be lower than under a centralized regime, but that each individual bribe will be larger than under the centralized regime. The implication for investment, growth, and development is that centralized corruption, while inefficient, is more efficient than decentralized corruption. There are now higher transactions costs to negotiating contracts and getting investment approval—without central coordination, it is less clear who to bribe, how much to bribe, or whether each bribe paid will be the last. For this and related 7 Interview with an official at an international development agency in Jakarta, March 2006. reasons, many observers consider the welfare-enhancing effects of regional splitting and decentralization to be ambiguous, if not negative.8 This perspective suggests a tantalizing hypothesis about the overall effect of decentralization on long-run economic growth. Could Indonesia’s decentralization actually be harmful to long-run growth by decoupling the many opportunities for bribery and extortion in the Indonesian economy from a strong, centralized leader? Consider first the trends in perceived corruption over time. Indonesia has always been one of the world’s most corrupt countries, consistently registering at the bottom of cross-national indices of corruption. Transparency International always places Indonesia in the bottom quartile of all countries, similar to many countries in Central Asia and many emerging markets in sub-Saharan Africa. On a scale of 1-10, with one the most corrupt and 10 the least, Indonesia averages around 2 (Table 1). Table 1: Indonesia, Corruption Scores, 1995-2005 Source: Transparency International 1995 1.9 8 1996 2.7 1997 2.7 1998 2.0 1999 1.7 2000 1.7 2001 1.9 2002 1.9 2003 1.9 2004 2.0 2005 2.2 See e.g. “Potret lima tahun pemekaran daerah,” Jawa Pos, November 21, 2005; “Semakin menjauh dari kesejahteraan rakyat,” Kompas, March 3, 2006; “Desain tak matang, desentralisasi jadi beban,” Kompas, March 20, 2006; Toto Suryaningtyas, “Laju otonomi dalam kekangan peraturan,” Kompas, March 20, 2006; “Wakil Rakyat, mari korupsi lewat celah UU,” Kompas, April 6, 2006; “Revisi PP Pemekaran Daerah,” Kompas, May 17, 2006. An interesting trend is apparent in the data. While Indonesia has transitioned to democracy and adopted a wide-ranging program of decentralization, and while Indonesia is slowly improving from the valley of 1.7 in 1999 and 2000, Transparency International rates it as more corrupt in 2005 than in 1996; that is, Indonesia has yet to recover to even its pre-crisis level of corruption. We can compare the time trend in corruption to investment approvals per year (Figure 3). 140000 120000 100000 Domestic Investment 80000 Foreign Investment 60000 40000 20000 0 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Figure 3: Indonesia, Domestic and Foreign Direct Investment Approvals, in Billions of Rupiah, 1993-2005 Source: Bank Indonesia Both foreign direct investment and domestic investment in Indonesia remain much lower in the wake of the crisis they were before the crisis. In a highly open, export-oriented economy such as Indonesia, this fall in investment is likely the single greatest cause of the country’s slower economic growth in the wake of the crisis. For example, the government revealed in March 2006 that of ninety crucial infrastructure projects for which the government has sought tenders, less than twenty percent had attracted any attention from investors. Shortly thereafter, World Bank President and former US Ambassador to Indonesia Paul Wolfowitz stated that corruption was the single greatest hindrance to investment in Indonesia.9 9 “Proyek didanai utang bakal terganggu,” Bisnis Indonesia, March 8, 2006; “Korupsi hambatan terbesar investasi,” Bisnis Indonesia, April 11, 2006. There are many reasons to be wary of generalizing from this simple correlation between stubbornly persistent corruption and the failure of investment in Indonesia to rebound in the decade after the Asian Financial Crisis. Cross-national data on corruption is notoriously unreliable, and the movements in the Transparency International series are quite small when compared to the overall range of possible scores. Moreover, there are certainly other factors that have influenced investment decisions in Indonesia, in particular the rise of China, India, and Vietnam as low-cost competitors for foreign direct investment. Additionally, as noted in the introduction, the breakdown of the New Order gave rise to open secessionist conflicts in three different provinces, and terrorists have attacked foreign interests in Java and Bali; such political strife has certainly given domestic and foreign investors pause.10 Since democratization, moreover, labor has been free to organize for better wages and working conditions, which may have driven away some investors who formerly enjoyed Indonesia’s controlled labor force.11 But other characteristics of post-Soeharto Indonesian politics suggest that decentralization has not been as successful as many hoped in attracting investment. Since his election, SBY’s administration and Indonesian business groups have repeatedly exhorted provincial and sub-provincial governments to adopt streamlined investment regulations.12 In 10 Stefanus Osa, “Investasi di tengah ketidakpastian,” Kompas, March 18, 2006. “Pengusaha tak rugikan buruh,” Kompas, March 29, 2006; “Solusi soal buruh dirumuskan,” Kompas, May 8, 2006. Survey evidence, though, suggests that labor activism and labor regulations are not the culprit for decreased investment; see “Regulasi tenaga kerja bukan faktor dominan,” Kompas, March 20, 2006. 12 “Belum ada visi untuk Indonesia Inkorporasi,” Kompas, February 13, 2006; “Paket deregulasi investasi diluncurkan,” Bisnis Indonesia, March 1, 2006; “Tidak ada jalan pintas membangun bisnis,” Kompas, March 1, 2006; “Permudah semua urusan,” Kompas, March 9, 2006; “Pemerintah ikut andil dalam perda bermasalah,” Kompas, March 10, 2006; “Pemda agar tinjau perda di sektor perdagangan,” Bisnis Indonesia, March 13, 2006; “Kadin desak elit politik ciptakan ketenangan usaha,” Bisnis Indonesia, March 23, 2006; “Dibentuk, tim kaji korupsi di daerah,” Kompas, March 25, 2006; “Perda di Bengkulu bebani pengusaha,” Bisnis Indonesia, March 27, 2006; “SBY: Banyak anggaran daerah konsumtif,” Bisnis Indonesia, March 29, 2006; “Pelaporan perda masih minim,” Kompas, March 29, 2006; “393 Perda bermasalah akan dibatalkan,” Kompas, April 6, 2006; “Praktik premanisme bebani pengusaha di daerah,” Bisnis Indonesia, April 6, 2006; “‘Paradigma pemda soal investor harus diubah’,” Bisnis Indonesia, May 9, 2006; “Reformasi pemda harus dipercepat,” Kompas, May 12, 2006; “‘Paket insentif Oktober belum berjalan’,” Bisnis Indonesia, May 17, 2006. For more encouraging views, see “Pemda mulai 11 April 2006, the central government announced two new regulations to facilitate regional growth, permitting regions to designate special economic zones without central government approval and forbidding regions from imposing any new taxes, and yet while regions can now issue permits to foreign direct investors, they must still seek approval from the central government.13 The fact that SBY and his Cabinet members continue to prevail upon regional administrations to embark on such reforms, and that the central government continues to shoulder the responsibility for creating a good investment climate for needed infrastructural investment through pro-investment regulations, indicates that decentralization itself is not yet having its desired impact.14 There are, then, two seemingly opposing claims. At the provincial and sub-provincial level, decentralization seems to be associated with lower corruption, but at the national level the country is as corrupt as ever, and the investment climate remains unattractive. One promising way to square these claims comes from Henderson and Kuncoro’s (2006) finding that only when Islamic parties win local elections does local corruption decline. Islamic parties such as Partai Keadilan Sejahtera (The Prosperous Justice Party) have a reputation as being less corrupt than other Indonesian political parties, and the mechanism through which they attract voters may be less their Islamist message than their commitment to government that is “clean and caring” (bersih dan peduli). If this is the case, then it suggests that at least in Indonesia, what makes decentralization effective is not inter-jurisdictional competition itself, but its combination with membenahi birokrasinya”, Kompas, April 11, 2006; “‘Iklim usaha di daerah membaik’,” Bisnis Indonesia, May 23, 2006. 13 “Daerah bisa bangun kawasan khusus,” Bisnis Indonesia, April 12, 2006; “Pemerintah daerah dilarang terbitkan perda pajak baru ,” Kompas, April 13, 2006; “Pemda boleh keluarkan izin investasi,” Bisnis Indonesia, April 17, 2006; “Standar izin investasi berlaku nasional,” Bisnis Indonesia, April 18, 2006. 14 “Paket insentif segera keluar,” Bisnis Indonesia, February 17, 2006; “Paket kebijakan infrastruktur,” Kompas, February 18, 2006; “BI: Rp708 triliun untuk menggerakkan ekonomi,” Bisnis Indonesia, February 22, 2006; “Pemerintah luncurkan paket kebijakan investasi”, Kompas, March 3, 2006; “Mendag keluarkan 8 aturan baru,” Bisnis Indonesia, March 31, 2006; “Swasta diajak ikut di zona ekonomi”, Kompas, March 31, 2006; “Bappenas: izin investasi akan kembali ke daerah,” Bisnis Indonesia, April 11, 2006; “‘Informasi investasi di daerah minim’,” Bisnis Indonesia, April 21, 2006; “‘Daya saing Indonesia masih rendah’,” Bisnis Indonesia, May 5, 2006; “Masih ada instansi tak rela melepaskan kewenangan”, Kompas, May 24, 2006; interview with Aburizal Bakrie, Coordinating Minister for People’s Welfare, March 14, 2006. local democracy and rotation of power. This still, however, leaves unexplained why decentralization and rotation of power have so far not led provinces to improve their investment climates. Perhaps the safest conclusion about Indonesia’s transition to democracy and the move to decentralization and regional autonomy is that their beneficial effects, at least until now, have been small and delayed. Provinces and sub-provincial administrations have been slow to adopt reforms that attract investment and combat Indonesia’s (relatively) high cost economy. Moreover, the level of corruption in Indonesia is still worrisome, and there is wide agreement among Indonesians that corruption is greatest threat to Indonesia’s macroeconomy. At the national level, decentralization cannot solve the problem of corruption, and Indonesian political leaders recognize that doing so requires firm action by the central government. There have been some encouraging steps. Successive governments have empowered supervisory agencies such as the Capital Market Supervisory Agency, the Finance and Development Supervisory Agency, and the Office of Public Accounts to combat financial improprieties, and reform of the country’s clumsy and corrupt tax collection agencies remains a high government priority. Yet many question these institutions’ ability to execute their tasks because of a lack of legal protection and unclear regulations.15 On corruption, Gus Dur and Megawati each created coordinating bodies to combat corruption, collusion, and nepotism, the most influential among them being the Corruption Eradication Commission, formed in 2002. SBY’s government has staked its reputation on eradicating corruption, and has created two new bodies, the Corruptors’ Search Team in 2004 and the Coordinating Team for the Eradication of Corrupt Practices in 2005. But results have been slow, with overlapping responsibilities, limited 15 “Pembentukan komisi independen pajak dipercepat,” Bisnis Indonesia, February 8, 2006; “IMF desak RI reformasi pajak ,” Bisnis Indonesia, February 20, 2006; “‘Peran KAP ungkap korupsi masih minim’,” Bisnis Indonesia, June 1, 2006. protection for witnesses, and a lack of coordination among the several extant anti-corruption agencies hindering successful prosecution of suspects (see Yuntho 2005b).16 While the Indonesian press issues new reports of corruption investigations almost daily, there are frequent criticisms that the most corrupt and politically connected figures escape prosecution.17 The on-going Bank Indonesia Liquidity Support scandal—referring to the massive amount of liquidity support doled out to cronies controlled banks at the height of the crisis—has yet to reach much of a conclusion. Some of the biggest corruptors simply vanished overseas, and others arranged to have their repossessed assets overvalued by government auditors in order to minimize their losses (Mintorahardjo 2001: 25-53; Yuntho 2005a).18 In other areas, despite several high profile cases in which corrupt politicians and businessmen have been convicted, the deterrent effect of national anti-corruption efforts seems minimal. For instance, Soeharto’s third son Tommy (Hutomo Mandala Putra) was sentenced in 2001 to eighteen months in prison for corruption, but for months he avoided detention. His corruption conviction was overturned, but not until after he masterminded the revenge killing of the Supreme Court Justice M. Syafiuddin Kartasasmita (who had presided over his first trial), a crime for which he was sentenced to fifteen years in prison. Tommy has served his sentence with relative ease, using funds from his Humpuss Group to build a badminton court on prison grounds, receiving extended visits from models, periodically using complaints of stomach pain to seek respites from 16 “KPK usul satukan pengadilan yang dua jalur,” Kompas, February 22, 2006; “Saksi pelapor bisa bebas,” Kompas, March 17, 2006. 17 “Presiden bantah berantas korupsi secara tebang pilih,” Kompas, February 6, 2006; “Tebang pilih karena kepentingan politik,” Kompas, February 16, 2006; “Pengadilan korupsi versus pengadilan umum,” Kompas, March 1, 2006; “Pemerintah dinilai tidak konsisten berantas korupsi,” Kompas, April 19, 2006. 18 “Korupsi BLBI gotong royong,” Kompas, May 23, 2003; “Six tycoons to have their BLBI cases closed,” Jakarta Post, July 28, 2004; “Tim baru akan urus aset bodong,” Kompas, February 6, 2006; “Mengungkit kembali penjualan aset BPPN”, Bisnis Indonesia, February 8, 2006; “Baru dua obligor serahkan dokumen,” Kompas, May 5, 2006; interview with Yosef Ardi, Reporter for Bisnis Indonesia, March 6, 2006. Some allege that debtors have used personal connections with SBY to protect their assets: “Debtor ke Istana, itu tidak etis,” Kompas, February 10, 2006. incarceration, and repeatedly earning sentence reductions.19 Were it not for Tommy’s decision to murder a judge, he would be free today, like his famously corrupt sister Tutut and his father, who has been repeatedly deemed too ill to stand trial. Under SBY, whose administration has undoubtedly done more to combat corruption than its predecessors, a troubling new trend is the bribery of legal officials associated with corruption investigations. Credible reports appear periodically that members of the Corruption Eradication Commission have accepted bribes and intimidated witnesses.20 Soeharto’s half-brother, Probosutedjo, confessed to bribing Chief Justice Bagir Manan, who presided over his corruption trial in 2003. Since then, prosecutors have brought charges against several Supreme Court employees, but Bagir remains untouched in the wake of jurisdictional spats between the Supreme Court and the Corruption Eradication Commission.21 A similar case involves Achmad Djunaidi, who as president of the state-owned workers’ insurance cooperative PT Jamsostek oversaw a number of shady investment deals that ultimately cost the Indonesian government more than Rp 200 billion (around US$21.6 million). Upon being sentenced to eight years in prison in April 2006, Achmad revealed that he had paid Rp 600 million (around US$65,000) to government lawyers as a bribe to avoid jail time.22 Two attorneys in the Attorney-General’s office have been dismissed, and may face questioning from the Corruption Eradication Commission, but the 19 “Soeharto’s son builds badminton court in jail,” Sydney Morning Herald, October 1, 2003; “Model banned from visiting Tommy,” Jakarta Post, August 6, 2004. Tommy’s lawyer Elsa Syarif, who helped hide him from police in 2001, has not been charged with any wrong-doing; “Police declare Adrian’s lawyer a suspect,” Jakarta Post, October 6, 2004. 20 “AKP Suparman mulai diadili,” Kompas, May 31, 2006. 21 “Suharto’s half-brother faces 4-year jail term in fraud case,” Asian Wall Street Journal, April 23, 2003; “Judge’s arrest a long time coming,” Jakarta Post, January 11, 2006; “Kasus suap di MA diajukan ke pengadilan”, Kompas, February 10, 2006; “Harini akui bertemu sendiri dengan Bagir Manan”, Kompas, March 10, 2006; Susana Rita, “Peradilan tetap saja korup,” Kompas, May 24, 2006; “Why it’s so difficult to eradicate corruption in Indonesia,” Jakarta Post, May 24, 2006. 22 “Mafia hancurkan peradilan,” Kompas, April 29, 2006; “Jaksa dituding terima uang,” Kompas, April 29, 2006; “Tim Tastipikor tangani dua jaksa ‘nakal’,” Kompas, May 20, 2006. blatant nature of the corruption involved raises concerns about the SBY administration’s ability to prosecute corruption cases successfully. In sum, we can draw several conclusions about the post-Soeharto Indonesian political economy. Government-business relations remain extremely close, and many of the big pribumi entrepreneurs from the New Order have risen in the government. But the institutional context of government-business relations has changed with decentralization and democratization. The national government must now negotiate with provincial governments, few of which have made great strides in improving the local investment climate. Corruption is now decentralized, and perhaps more growth retarding than corruption under the New Order. There is tentative evidence that local corruption has decreased with decentralization and local political competition, but at the national level it still remains the greatest threat to Indonesia’s macroeconomic stability, even given the SBY administration’s attempts to bring corrupt politicians and business figures to justice. Perhaps ironically, these vulnerabilities are what will probably shield Indonesia from the same sort of meltdown that it experienced in 1997-1998, as foreign and domestic investors are far more hesitant to invest in Indonesia than in the mid-1990s. Indonesia’s vulnerability is now of a different sort: that of a low-investment, low-growth equilibrium that undoes public support for democracy and regional autonomy.23 4. Malaysia: Institutional Continuity and Macroeconomic Vulnerability Economic recovery in concert with political repression allowed Mahathir’s regime to withstand a political challenge from Anwar and a newly galvanized political opposition. The engine of this political opposition was Malaysia’s reformasi movement, which championed the causes of reform and social justice and catalyzed the formation of the Barisan Alternatif 23 See recent data from Mujani (2006) for evidence that Indonesia’s slow growth negatively influences Indonesians’ support for democracy. (Alternative Front, BA), an electoral coalition among the Pan-Malaysian Islamic Party (PAS), the largely Chinese Democratic Action Party (DAP), and the pan-ethnic National Justice Party (Keadilan) founded by Anwar’s wife Wan Azizah Wan Ismail. In the 1999 general elections, PAS captured an additional state legislature for a total of two out of thirteen, and expanded its small share of seats in Malaysia’s lower house. Yet the ruling Barisan Nasional (National Front, BN) coalition, led by UMNO and Mahathir, easily retained the two-thirds majority in the lower house that it had enjoyed since the suspension of democracy in 1969. In the wake of the BN’s victory, Mahathir moved against many of his political opponents (Abbott 2004: 80-81; Committee to Protect Journalists 2000; Netto 1999), reinforcing his firm grip over Malaysian politics and society. Mahathir continued to rule until 2003, when he handed the reigns of power to Deputy Prime Minister Abdullah Ahmad Badawi. Abdullah led the BN to an overwhelming victory in the 2004 general elections, reaffirming UMNO and the BN’s position at the apex of Malaysia’s regime. This political continuity means that at the institutional level, Malaysia’s political economy has changed little between 1996 and 2006. On one hand, this has provided a boon to investment (Figure 4), as foreign and domestic companies continue to be attracted to the country’s relative political stability and quiescent labor force. 35000 30000 25000 Domestic Investment 20000 Foreign Investment in Approved Projects 15000 10000 5000 0 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Figure 4: Malaysia, Domestic and Foreign Direct Investment (in Millions of Ringgit), 1993-2004 Source: Ministry of Finance The data show that like in Indonesia, foreign investment declined in 1997, but unlike Indonesia, has since recovered to beyond pre-crisis levels. The spikes in domestic investment reflect expansionary fiscal policies launched by the government in 1998 and again in 2001. But in contrast to this favorable picture of investment recovery which has driven Malaysia’s post-crisis economic growth, political continuity in Malaysia means that there has been little meaningful reform in the policy areas that contributed to the country’s macroeconomic vulnerability in the late 1990s. Table 2: Malaysia, Corruption Scores, 1995-2005 Source: Transparency International 1995 5.3 1996 5.3 1997 5.0 1998 5.3 1999 5.1 2000 4.8 2001 5.0 2002 4.9 2003 5.2 2004 5.0 2005 5.1 As measured by Transparency International, for example, Malaysia is almost precisely as corrupt in 2005 as it was in 1995—although, like Indonesia, corruption worsened in the wake of the country’s economic crisis before making a modest recovery. The increase in corruption from 1999 through 2002 stems largely from measures that the regime took to foster economic recovery. While capital controls and expansionary macroeconomic policy allowed the regime to jumpstart economic growth, they also allowed the regime to rescue politically connected firms without the fear of punishment from foreign traders. To resolve outstanding issues of corporate debt and weak financial institutions, the government created two quasi-governmental bodies tasked with acquiring non-performing loans and injecting capital into weak banks (Danaharta and Danamodal). A Corporate Debt Restructuring Committee facilitated these tasks (see Mahani 2002). But there was clear evidence of favoritism in these bodies’ operations. The government bought out shares in the deeply indebted Malaysian Airlines Systems from Tajudin Ramli, a corporate ally of former Finance Minister Daim Zainuddin, at an inflated price that allowed Tajudin to pay off his own extensive debts.24 The government also bought a controlling stake in Time dotCom Bhd, using public funds to complement private investment after a failed initial public offering.25 Time dotCom is a subsidiary of Time Engineering Bhd, in turn controlled by the government-linked conglomerate Renong Bhd, which had long been one of UMNO’s corporate arms. Just six months later, after a falling out between Mahathir and Daim, the government bought a controlling stake in Renong, which itself remained mired deeply in debt.26 Such examples abound of Mahathir’s regime using public funds to protect political interests during this period of recovery. Johnson and Mitton (2003) find that the stock prices of publicly listed companies with links to Mahathir recovered faster than stock prices of unaffiliated firms, and that both recovered faster than stock prices of firms associated with Anwar. The onset of Abdullah’s tenure in office was a moment of optimism for many observers of Malaysian politics (Welsh 2005). Under his leadership, the final remnants of Malaysia’s radical adjustment measures—bans on short-selling of stocks and the ringgit’s hard peg to the 24 “MAS rescue faces a difficult course,” Asian Wall Street Journal, January 17, 2001. “Malaysian funds buy costly stake in Time dotCom,” Asian Wall Street Journal, March 16, 2001. 26 Terence Gomez, “Malaysia Inc.: Bailout or accountability?,” Asian Wall Street Journal, July 26, 2001. 25 US dollar—have been lifted. He has a reputation of being personally incorruptible, and he immediately embarked on an ambitious program to streamline government-linked companies (GLCs) and root out public sector inefficiency. On these counts, he can claim some modest success, having introduced procurement standards and efficiency guidelines and replaced ineffective executives in some GLCs.27 Yet close examination of Malaysian politics and economic management shows that the tight relationship between business and politics persists. Several promised reforms have yet to come to pass, such as the establishment of an open tender system for government procurement and a fair competition law.28 While the late 1980s saw official privatization of many companies, the government retains a large stake in conglomerates in key sectors. Some government-controlled firms such as Telekom Malaysia Berhad (telecommunications) and Petronas (petroleum exploration and refining) are notably professional and have expanded beyond Malaysia’s borders, but others such as Tenaga Nasional Berhad (power generation) have retained their influence through size rather than efficiency.29 Furthermore, political favoritism granted to clearly inefficient companies such as the national automobile company Proton persists, reflecting both the continued influence of Mahathir on daily politics (he is now Proton’s “special advisor”) and Abdullah’s inability to combat entrenched interests.30 27 “Professional managers,” New Straits Times, February 20, 2004; “PM: we must be thrifty,” The Star, March 7, 2006; “Committee: GLCs must stress more on transparency,” The Star, March 10, 2006; “Taking efficiency to the highest level,” New Straits Times, April 2, 2006; “Manuals to help boost performance of govt-linked firms,” Business Times, April 26, 2006; “PM: Better procurement can save GLCs billions,” New Straits Times, April 27, 2006; “Star rating to assess ministries’ services,” New Straits Times, May 2, 2006. There has been some discussion of further rounds of privatization, but this is unlikely to occur in the near future; “Khazanah kaji kemungkinan GLC jadi firma persendirian,” Berita Harian, March 24, 2006; “9MP: initiative for privatisation,” The Star, April 1, 2006. 28 “Malaysia risk: legal & regulatory risk,” Economist Intelligence Unit – Risk Briefing, May 23, 2006. Interview with Lim Kit Siang, DAP MP, July 12, 2006; interview with Tan Sri Ramon Navaratnam, President of Transparency International (Malaysia), July 17, 2006. 29 “Tenaga stock may be capped at current levels,” Asian Wall Street Journal, October 6, 2004; “Tarif baru elektrik tidak jejaskan rakyat miskin,” Berita Harian, March 4, 2006; “Mounting woes for TNB,” April 12, 2006. 30 “Proton terus dibantu,” Berita Harian, March 24, 2006; “Cheaper Protons,” New Straits Times, March 25, 2006; “Proton pledges to reduce defects,” The Star, April 6, 2006. From the standpoint of UMNO’s leadership, control over budgetary purse strings has reached paramount importance. As part of his strategy to sideline Anwar, Mahathir took temporary control of the Ministry of Finance, and later gave the Finance portfolio to his longtime ally Daim Zainuddin, a Malay businessman who built his billion dollar fortune through a close association with UMNO leaders and who had previously occupied this position from 1984 to 1991. Daim served until 2001, when Mahathir assumed the position himself. Daim ostensibly resigned on his own accord, but political observers have noted that Daim’s business interests had come into conflict with the business interests of Mahathir’s son Mokhzani Mahathir.31 Since rising to the position of Prime Minister, Abdullah has continued Mahathir’s practice of holding the Finance portfolio. Also of note is the continued existence of the National Economic Action Council (NEAC), a super-constitutional organ that Mahathir created in late 1997 to find a solution to the country’s economic crisis. Although the crisis has long since abated, the NEAC continues to exist as a body with wide discretionary authority over economic management, superseding that of economic ministries such as Trade and Industry, Public Works, Finance, and others. At the head of its Executive Committee sits the Prime Minister, the Deputy Prime Minister, and an executive chair who also serves as Minister in the Prime Minister’s Department. If anything, this is evidence of more political centralization of economic policy formation than under Mahathir’s rule before the crisis. Besides maintaining the high level of centralization in economic policy making, Abdullah has retained a number of Mahathir’s cronies who had under Mahathir served as members of his economic team. Rafidah Aziz, a long time Mahathir loyalist with several corruption scandals already under her belt, remains Abdullah’s Minister of International Trade and Industry. S. Samy Vellu, President of the BN’s Indian component party the Malaysian Indian Congress and a 31 See Terence Gomez, “Why Mahathir axed Daim,” Asian Wall Street Journal, July 5, 2001. figure long noted for his egregious use of patronage to secure office,32 has retained his influential position as the Minister of Public Works. Abdullah has retained other figures as well, leading many observers to question Abdullah’s independence from the UMNO party machine.33 Such continuity of Malaysian politics reveals that despite Abdullah’s reputation as a clean politician without crony linkages to the business community, opposition from entrenched interests in UMNO and the BN makes it unlikely that he will introduce wide ranging and effective reforms. Moreover, Abdullah’s son-in-law Khairy Jamaluddin, viewed as having extraordinary personal influence over Abdullah, has seen his personal wealth grow extensively since 2004 at what many believe to be shady investment deals dependent on political favoritism.34 Additionally, Abdullah’s deputy Najib Abdul Razak has none of Abdullah’s reputation for moderation and clean government. Instead, he is known as a staunch defender of Malay special rights and of UMNO, and is often identified with the politics of his father, Abdul Razak Hussein, who engineered the move toward overt UMNO dominance of Malaysian politics during the period of suspended democracy from 1969-1971. If the personal inclinations of power holders (aside from Abdullah) are less than encouraging, developments in the government’s intervention in the economy reveal that the main institutional weaknesses of the Malaysian government have persisted as well. The regime has not retreated from its long advocacy of Malay political dominance and favoritism for Malays in business and society. (In Malaysia, “positive discrimination” officially benefits all bumiputras, or non-Chinese and non-Indians, but Malays are the main beneficiaries of this favoritism.) A 32 “Troubled run-up to MIC elections,” New SundayTimes, April 16, 2006. “Despite landslide election, some officials are retained from Mahathir’s regime,” Asian Wall Street Journal, March 29, 2004; “Malaysia—Not so fast,” Far Eastern Economic Review, April 8, 2004; “Minor Cabinet reshuffle,” New Straits Times, February 14, 2006; “Mixed reactions from the public on new Cabinet line-up,” The Star, February 15, 2006. 34 Anonymous interview with a Malaysian economist, July 2006. 33 revealing document is the Ninth Malaysia Plan (Government of Malaysia 2006), Malaysia’s first five-year development plan issued under Abdullah, which the government released to great domestic fanfare in February 2006. The Plan, like its predecessors, places heavy emphasis on the government’s role in coordinating the redistribution of wealth and equity in favor of bumiputras, largely at the expense of the country’s large Chinese Malaysian minority.35 There are many ways in which the government intervenes in the economy to sponsor interethnic redistribution, many of which have created macroeconomic vulnerabilities in the past. For instance, in a worrying continuation of policies long implemented under Mahathir and his predecessors, the government continues to manage a number of bumiputra-only unit trusts with heavy involvement in the KLSE. Mahathir himself directed the expansion of government participation in the stock market in the late 1990s and early 2000s as yet another way to increase the wealth flowing to Malays in the wake of the country’s financial crisis. Besides the unit trusts that had existed for years before Malaysia’s crisis (Amanah Saham Nasional and Amanah Saham Bumiputra), the government subsidiary Permodalan Nasional Berhad (PNB) launched two more in 2000 and 2001. PNB also manages four unit trusts open to all Malaysians, including Amanah Saham Wawasan 2020 (launched in 1996) and three others launched between 2000 and 2003. But even the pan-ethnic government unit trusts reserve many shares for bumiputras at discounted prices. Besides PNB’s capital market investments, the government maintains an active interest in the corporate world in other ways. Khazanah Nasional Berhad, incorporated in 1993 under the Ministry of Finance, undertakes “strategic investments” in areas such as power generation, 35 “Priority on acquiring a first-class mentality,” The Star, April 1, 2006. One interesting development is that for the first time Indian Malaysians have been identified as requiring government assistance, “9th Malaysia Plan: Yearly economic growth of 6 pc,” New Straits Times, April 1, 2006; “Business training for Bumiputeras and Indians,” New Straits Times, May 23, 2006. shipping, transportation, and many others. Perbadanan Nasional Berhad (PNS), formerly under the Ministry of Finance before privatization in 1996, facilitates the growth of a “bumiputra commercial and industrial community” by investing in bumiputra-controlled start-ups and distributing franchises to bumiputras. Perbadanan Usahawan Nasional Berhad (PUNB), a wholly owned subsidiary of Yayasan Pelaburan Bumiputra (of which PNB is another subsidiary), has since 1991 complemented PNS in nurturing bumiputra entrepreneurs, and its responsibility for creating bumiputra franchisees and businesses owners expanded notably in the Ninth Malaysia Plan.36 Below the federal level, State Economic Development Corporations (SEDCs) perform similar functions within most Malaysian states. A wide array of government linked coordinating bodies and policy development organizations support these efforts both at the Federal level and among the Malaysian states.37 The principal-agent danger from such extensive government involvement in the Malaysian business sector is precisely the same today as it was a decade ago. PNB, Khazanah, PUNB, the SEDCs, and even PNS are all subordinate to politicians, and despite Abdullah’s vocal commitment to efficiency and “the national interest,” the politicians that oversee these government bodies may have interests at loggerheads with that of the Malaysian people, the firms’ supposed beneficiaries. In the past, politicians have influenced national investment companies to invest in uneconomical business ventures connected to political allies. Additionally, because the regime has such a direct stake in the performance of Malaysian stocks, it has a strong incentive to protect dividends at all costs. From the perspective of the recipients of patronage, political favoritism breeds moral hazard. And while many governments across the 36 37 “2,420 perniagaan diwujud,” Berita Harian, May 2, 2006. “Insken, MPUD mampu mempercepat kuasai ekonomi,” Berita Harian, May 24, 2006. world have quasi-corporate subsidiaries that facilitate strategic national investments, the danger in Malaysia comes from the country’s weak regulatory apparatus. Regulatory weaknesses are the result of technical incompetence, but rather of the vulnerability of supervisory agencies to political interference. Bank Negara Malaysia, Malaysia’s Central Bank, is by no means independent from political influence (during the 1998 crisis political pressure led its Governor and Deputy Governor to resign). Agencies of public accountability such as the Anti-Corruption Agency (ACA), the Federal Courts, and the Electoral Commission (EC) remain subordinate to high UMNO office holders. The ACA has the statutory authority to investigate and prosecute a wide number of offenses among public servants, but in practice, it is successful against only low-level functionaries.38 The Malaysian judiciary, stripped of independent authority by Mahathir in the late 1980s but tentatively reasserting its independence since 2004, still under Abdullah faces not infrequent accusations of bowing to political pressure and bribery.39 The Electoral Commission still encounters widespread criticism from opposition parties and NGOs, most recently for shady voter registration practices in Sarawak’s 2006 state elections.40 In the 1980s and 1990s, such weak regulatory bodies fostered the growth of corruption and money politics, and observers uncovered a number of corporate scandals tied directly to UMNO and other BN component parties (see Gomez 1994; Gomez and Jomo 1999; Milne and Mauzy 1999; Searle 1999). During the crisis, Mahathir used these and other investment arms to protect the interests of favored groups, using for example funds from Khazanah and the publicly owned pension fund the Employees’ Provident Fund to shore up the 38 “First civil servant to be charged with not declaring assets,” New Straits Times, February 14, 2006; “At the Dewan Rakyat yesterday: arrests for graft increasing,” New Straits Times, March 21, 2006. 39 “Justice for sale: Are some judges corrupt?,” New Straits Times, May 31, 2006. 40 “Suspend elections, Kit Siang tells EC,” Malaysiakini, May 20, 2006; “Revamp EC, says election watchdog,” Malaysiakini, May 25, 2006.. sagging KLSE.41 In other words, without prudential oversight, Malaysia’s economy in the 1990s expanded recklessly, leading to macroeconomic vulnerabilities; today, without meaningful reform, the same danger exists. Several recent corporate scandals reveal that political protection remains valuable for well-connected corporate figures. In the case of Daim Zainuddin, his falling-out with UMNO power holders appears to have left him particularly vulnerable. In January 2006, the Court of Appeals ruled that Metramac Corporation Sdn Bhd (formerly Syarikat Teratai K.G. Sdn Bhd), controlled by Daim’s protégés Halim Saad and Annuar Othman, owed RM65 million to Fawziah Holdings Sdn Bhd for losses incurred in a scrapped highway construction project from 1990. Daim as Finance Minister had informed the directors of Fawziah—a main investor in Syarikat Teratai—that the government had insufficient funds to pay compensation for the project. Halim and Annuar then purchased Syarikat Teratai for a deflated price, after which Daim announced that the government would pay the compensation after all. The key to this transaction was Halim and Annuar’s personal connections to Daim, which allowed them to make tens of millions of ringgit instantly at Fawziah’s expense.42 Halim, Annuar, and Daim immediately appealed court’s ruling, and Daim firmly denied that Halim or Annuar had ever benefited from connections with him during his tenure as the Minister of Finance.43 This statement certainly conflicts with the many questionable contracts awarded to Halim’s United Engineers (Malaysia) Berhad, a subsidiary of Renong (see above), throughout the 1980s and 1990s (Gomez 2002: 9195; Jomo 1998: 187). The case has yet to reach a conclusion, but it is revealing that the case against Daim moved forward only after he fell from political favor. 41 “RM60b sokong BSKL,” Utusan Malaysia, September 4, 1997. “Metramac to pay RM65m,” New Straits Times, January 13, 2006; “KL politics-business link exposed in court,” Straits Times, January 16, 2006. 43 “Daim: it was Cabinet’s decision,” The Star, January 27, 2006. 42 Under Abdullah, moreover, political scandals reveal also that the practice of UMNO politicians using their office for corporate gain remains widespread. In 2005, Mahathir revealed the extensive use of approved permits (APs) for importing foreign-made automobiles into the country as important new tool of political patronage. The distribution of APs falls under the authority of Minister of International Trade and Industry Rafidah Aziz. Mahathir, as Proton’s advisor, condemned the practice for introducing competition to Malaysia’s heavily protected domestic automobile industry, and released the names of the beneficiaries of over 67,000 APs issued in 2004 alone. Despite extensive media coverage, no charges of wrongdoing have been filed, and Rafidah has retained her position.44 In another scandal, the Malaysian press revealed in May 2006 that UMNO parliamentarian Mohd Said Yusof had requested that Malacca Customs and Excise officials “close one eye” to the import of illegal Indonesian sawn logs by a company that he owned. This is not Mohd Said’s first brush with the authorities over illegal trade, as customs officials in 1999 charged a company of which he is a director with illegally exporting pirated VCDs to Indonesia. Yet even though Mohd Said admitted abusing his political power, the BN refused to endorse an opposition recommendation to refer Mohd Said to the Parliamentary Privileges committee.45 These political developments lead most observers to question the true extent to which Abdullah is able to combat corruption and patronage in Malaysian politics. So in contrast to the case of Indonesia, in Malaysia we find that institutional continuity has contributed to a more rapid recovery from the crisis, at the cost of continued if not additional macroeconomic vulnerabilities. The link between Malaysia’s political system and 44 “Committee fully responsible for APs, says Pak Lah,” The Star, February 18, 2006. “I asked Customs to close one eye: Jasin MP,” Malaysiakini, May 4, 2006; “Let other agencies investigate,” New Sunday Times, May 7, 2006; “Mohd Said admits owning Binyu Sof,” New Straits Times, May 11, 2006; “Firm once hauled up over smut VCDs,” New Straits Times, May 12, 2006; author interview with Datuk Shahrir Abdul Samad, BN MP for Johore Bahru and former Chairman of the BN Backbenchers’ Club, July 10, 2006. 45 macroeconomic vulnerability is easy to miss in relatively fat times, but it is important to recall that Malaysia’s economic crisis from 1997-1999 began following a similar period of seemingly healthy expansion. Like Indonesia, though, the memory of the near-collapse of Malaysia’s economy still gives foreign investors pause, and risk consultancies continue to warn that the dark areas of Malaysia’s political economy have persisted under Abdullah. If anything shields Malaysia from financial and real sector crises today, it is investor wariness, not political and economic reform. 5. Conclusions The experiences of Indonesia and Malaysia after the Asian Financial Crisis reveal the difficulty of establishing institutions that can sponsor healthy economic growth. Indonesia since 1998 has experienced rapid and far-ranging institutional change towards institutions that scholarly consensus holds should be both welfare and efficiency enhancing. But its experience suggests that the benefits of democratization and decentralization can be delayed, both by extensive corruption and the difficult task of adjusting to these new institutional arrangements. Malaysia’s experience reaffirms what many consider an uncomfortable common wisdom that despite their high costs in terms of personal freedoms, selective repression and autocratic political stability can be a platform for economic recovery. In both countries, corruption and government-business linkages remain the greatest source of macroeconomic vulnerability, and the level of corruption in 2005 in each is the same as it was before the Asian Financial Crisis. But corruption has changed in Indonesia from a highly centralized system of hierarchical exchange to a decentralized system of bribery and influence peddling. In Malaysia, the main players have changed with the resignation of Mahathir, the marginalization of Anwar and Daim, and the rise of Abdullah and Khairy, but the system has proven remarkably resilient. If the discussion here appears pessimistic, one welcome sign in both countries is the rise of an active civil society. Civil society in these two countries plays a vital role in monitoring government excesses and agitating for reform. Hundreds of NGOs have sprung up in Indonesia to agitate for clean government, such as the influential Indonesian Corruption Watch which has taken the lead in tracking and publicizing cases of corruption.46 In Malaysia, draconian legislation that restricts civil society organizing remains in effect, but opposition presses and NGOs energized by the country’s reformasi movement still vocally criticize the BN regime, and even the government-controlled print media have become bolder in covering political and economic scandals since 2004. While evidence of its impact on policies that minimize macroeconomic vulnerability remains scarce, the ability of nascent civil society groups to help improve government accountability to popular demands for clean and responsible government may be the key to fostering macroeconomic stability and healthy long-run economic growth in Indonesia and Malaysia. 6. References Abbott, Jason P. 2004. The Internet, Reformasi and Democratisation in Malaysia. In The State of Malaysia: Ethnicity, Equity and Reform, edited by Edmund Terence Gomez. London: RoutledgeCurzon. Berg, Andrew. 1999. The Asian crisis: Causes, policy responses, and outcomes. IMF Working Paper WP/99/138. Committee to Protect Journalists. 2000. Malaysia. Available online at http://www.cpj.org/attacks00/asia00/Malaysia.html [Accessed May 1, 2006]. Crouch, Harold. 1978. The Army and Politics in Indonesia. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Fisman, Raymond, and Roberta Gatti. 2002. Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence Across Countries. Journal of Public Economics 83:325-345. Gomez, Edmund Terence. 1994. Political Business: Corporate Involvement Of Malaysian Political Parties. Townsville, Queensland, Australia: Centre for South-East Asian Studies, James Cook University of North Queensland. ---. 2002. Political Business in Malaysia: Party Factionalism, Corporate Development, and Economic Crisis. In Political Business in East Asia, edited by Edmund Terence Gomez. London: Routledge. 46 “ICW laporkan 133 hakim ke Komisi Yudisial,” Kompas, May 15, 2006. Gomez, Edmund Terence, and K. S. Jomo. 1999. Malaysia's Political Economy: Politics, Patronage and Profits. Second ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Government of Malaysia. 2006. Ninth Malaysia Plan 2006-2010. Putrajaya: The Economic Planning Unit, Prime Minister's Department. Henderson, J. Vernon, and Ari Kuncoro. 2004. Corruption in Indonesia. NBER Working Paper Number 10674. ---. 2006. Sick of Local Government Corruption? Vote Islamic. NBER Working Paper Number 12110. Johnson, Simon, and Todd Mitton. 2003. Cronyism and Capital Controls: Evidence from Malaysia. Journal of Financial Economics 67 (??):351-382. Jomo, K.S. 1998. Malaysia: From Miracle to Debacle. In Tigers in Trouble: Financial Governance and the Crises in East Asia, edited by Jomo K. S. London: Zed Books Ltd. Jomo, K.S., and Natasha Hamilton-Hart. 2001. Financial Regulation, Crisis and Policy Response. In Malaysian Eclipse: Economic Crisis and Recovery, edited by Jomo K.S. London: Zed Books Ltd. Kaplan, Ethan, and Dani Rodrik. 2001. Did the Malaysian Capital Controls Work? NBER Working Paper No. 8142. Krugman, Paul. 1999. Capital Control Freaks: How Malaysia Got Away With Economic Heresy. Available online at http://slate.msn.com/id/35534/ [Accessed October 24, 2004]. Liddle, R. William. 1991. The Relative Autonomy of the Third World Politician: Soeharto and Indonesian Economic Development in Comparative Perspective. International Studies Quarterly 35 (4):403-427. ---. 2001. Indonesia in 2000: A Shaky Start for Democracy. Asian Survey 41 (1):208-220. MacIntyre, Andrew. 2000. Funny Money: Fiscal Policy, Rent-seeking and Economic Performance in Indonesia. In Rents, Rent-Seeking and Economic Development: Theory and Evidence in Asia, edited by Mushtaq H. Khan and Jomo K. S. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ---. 2003. Institutions and the Political Economy of Corruption in Developing Countries. Discussion paper, Workshop on Corruption, Stanford University, January 31-February 1, 2003. Mackie, Jamie, and Andrew MacIntyre. 1994. Politics. In Indonesia's New Order: The Dynamics of Socio-economic Transformation, edited by Hal Hill. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Mahani, Zainal Abidin. 2002. Rewriting the Rules: The Malaysian Crisis Management Model. Petaling Jaya, Selangor, Malaysia: Pearson Malaysia Sdn. Bhd. Malley, Michael. 2002. Indonesia in 2001: Restoring Stability in Jakarta. Asian Survey 42 (1):124-132. Martinez, Patricia. 2002. Malaysia in 2001: An Interlude of Consolidation. Asian Survey 42 (1):133-140. Milne, R.S., and Diane K. Mauzy. 1999. Malaysian Politics under Mahathir. London: Routledge. Mintorahardjo, Sukowaluyo. 2001. BLBI Simalakama: Pertaruhan Kekuasaan Presiden Soeharto. Jakarta: Penerbit RESI. Mujani, Saiful. 2006. Mengkonsolidasikan Demokrasi Indonesia: Refleksi Satu Windu Reformasi. Working Paper, Lembaga Survei Indonesia. Available online at http://www.lsi.or.id/file_download/19 [Accessed May 26, 2006]. Netto, Anil. 1999. A Y2K Crackdown: Arrests of Critics A Sign of Nervousness Ahead of UMNO Polls. Aliran Monthly 19 (11/12):2-6. Robison, Richard, and Vedi R. Hadiz. 2004. Reorganizing Power in Indonesia: The Politics of Oligarchy in an Age of Markets. London: RoutledgeCurzon. Searle, Peter. 1999. The Riddle of Malaysian Capitalism: Rent-Seekers or Real Capitalists? St Leonards, NSW: Allen & Unwin. Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny. 1993. Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3):599-617. Tiebout, Charles. 1956. A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy 64:416-424. Weingast, Barry R. 1995. The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Market-Preserving Federalism and Economic Development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 11:1-31. Welsh, Bridget. 2005. Malaysia in 2004: Out of Mahathir's Shadow? Asian Survey 45 (1):153160. Yuntho, Emerson. 2005a. Korupsi BLBI dan Persidangan In Absentia. Available online at http://www.antikorupsi.org/mod.php?mod=publisher&op=viewarticle&artid=6351 [Accessed June 1, 2006]. ---. 2005b. Tim Koordinasi Pemberantasan Korupsi: Antara Harapan dan Kekhawatiran. Available online at http://www.antikorupsi.org/docs/timtastipikoreson.pdf [Accessed May 24, 2006]. Iron Cage in an Iron Fist: Authoritarian Institutions and the Personalization of Power in Malaysia Author(s): Dan Slater Source: Comparative Politics, Vol. 36, No. 1 (Oct., 2003), pp. 81-101 Published by: Ph.D. Program in Political Science of the City University of New York Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4150161 . Accessed: 31/07/2013 09:47 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. . Ph.D. Program in Political Science of the City University of New York is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Comparative Politics. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Iron Cage in an Iron Fist of Powerin Institutionsandthe Personalization Authoritarian Malaysia Dan Slater "The individualbureaucrat....isonly a single cog in an ever-movingmechanism which prescribesto him an essentially fixed route of march.The official is entrusted with specialized tasks and normallythe mechanism cannotbe put in motion or arrestedby him, but only from the very top." Max Weber1 "Contraryto the usual belief that I am a dictator,I actuallywork as a team." MahathirMohamad2 Democraticinstitutionshave long enjoyed pride of place in comparativepolitics. By comparison,authoritarianinstitutionsremain inadequatelyconceptualized,theorized, and investigated. To help narrow this gap, this article assesses the conceptual and theoretical implications of a puzzling phenomenon: Malaysian Prime Minister MahathirMohamad'sgrowing personalizationof power since the mid 1980s. This phenomenon is particularlypuzzling because Malaysia has long represented one of the most institutionalizedparty-statesin the developing world, and personalization is typically seen as antitheticalto institutionalization.3While this conventional wisdom makes a great deal of sense in democracies, it is misleading in polities that exhibit significant authoritariancharacteristicssuch as Malaysia.4This distinction has importantimplicationsin understandinghow and why authoritarianregimes change, remain stable, or collapse. Since democratic and authoritarianinstitutions serve very different purposes, institutionalizationhas very different implications in democratic and authoritarian contexts. Democratic institutions fundamentallyserve to provide stable patterns of popularrepresentation.One way they accomplish this purpose is by constrainingthe chief executive's "despotic power,"which in the terminology of Michael Mann is "the range of actions" that an individual leader "is empoweredto take without routine, institutionalized negotiations" with other regime members.5 In democracies, therefore, personalization is antithetical to institutionalization by definition. 81 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October2003 Democracies can either be institutionalized,if rules constrainthe ruler, or personalized, if rulersignore the rules. Highly institutionalized authoritarianregimes also typically exhibit regularized succession mechanisms and collective decision-making procedures that curtail a ruler's personal power. But they are neither the sole nor the primary purposes of authoritarianinstitutions. Whereas democratic institutions serve to provide predictable patternsof representation,authoritarianinstitutions primarilyserve to provide a stable basis for domination.6The raison d'etre of authoritarianinstitutionsis not to constrain "despotic power,"but to supply a regime with the "infrastructural power"necessary to implement its command over potential opposition in civil society and within the multiple layers of the state apparatusitself.7 While democratic institutions serve to keep the executive in check, authoritarianinstitutionsserve to keep political opposition underwraps. Personalizationand institutionalizationare thus not as antitheticalin authoritarian regimes as in democracies. Despotic power (the power to decide) can become highly personalized,even as infrastructuralpower (the power to implement)remainshighly institutionalized.Institutionsto curtail the chief executive may falter while institutions to curtailpolitical oppositionremainformidable. This reconceptualizationof authoritarianinstitutionshelps addressa centraltheoretical puzzle. How can an aspiringautocratpersonalize power in the face of powerful preexisting institutions?8In other words, why would a bureaucratic"iron cage" fail to keep an autocratic"iron fist" in check? If political institutionsare conceived as procedural checks on the executive, personalization can occur only when a regime's institutionsare weak. But once authoritarianinstitutionsare gearedprimarily toward extending a regime's infrastructuralpower, personalization might take place when a regime's key institutionsare strong.Aspiring autocratscan not do their own dirty work; they need infrastructuralpower, embodied in regime organizations, to execute their commands.Therefore,in authoritarianregimes, high levels of infrastructural power facilitate the effective concentration of despotic power. Institutionalizationalong one dimension ironically abets deinstitutionalizationalong another. Recent events in Malaysia provide strong evidence in supportof this proposition. Because of its high antecedent level of institutionalization, Malaysia provides an ideal case to challenge the assumptionthat personalizationsignifies the underdevelopment of political institutions.9MahathirMohamad has confounded this conventional wisdom by establishinghighly personalizedcontrol over decision-makingprocedures in the Malaysian party-state. More specifically, Mahathirhas used three mechanisms of personalization-packing, rigging, and circumventing-to transform what was long described as a semidemocratic single party regime into something more closely resemblingpersonalizedauthoritarianrule. Mahathirhas personalized power as much by deploying Malaysia'sauthoritarian 82 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater institutions as by destroyingits democraticones, however.To the extent that institutions such as parliament,the judiciary,the cabinet, the bureaucracy,the sultans, the media, the police, and the ruling party (the United Malays National Organization,or UMNO) have historically served as democratic institutions-as procedural checks on despotic executive power-they have clearly been weakened.10But to the extent that these institutions historically served as authoritarianinstitutions-as the partystate's organizationalbasis for political control over potential opposition, including dissent from within the party-stateitself-they have served as much as Mahathir's accomplices as his victims. Moreover, Malaysia's political institutions have long acted, at least in part, as vehicles for top-down control. Even before MahathirtransformedMalaysia into a system of "pseudo-democracy"or "competitive authoritarianism"in the late 1990s, Malaysia was never considered fully democratic.11Rather, it was characterizedby knowledgeableobserversas a "quasi-democracy,"a "semidemocracy,"a "repressiveThe Malaysian partyresponsive regime," or a system of "soft authoritarianism."'2 state'skey institutionshave thereforeplayed a complex and dynamic combination of democraticand authoritarianroles for nearly five decades. Thus, when Mahathirfaced rising opposition to his increasinglypersonalized and authoritarianrule in 1998-99, he did not face the challenge in an institutionalvacuum. Rather,he confrontedit with the full assistance of a well-developed apparatusof party-state organizations that has exhibited a long institutional history of nipping opposition in the bud.13Most important,Mahathirinheriteda British colonial legacy of expansive emergency-style powers (most notoriously, the draconian Internal SecurityAct), as well as highly developed coercive organizationsunder tight hierarchical control, especially the federal police.14 If Mahathirchooses to crush rather than accommodate his personal rivals, he can count on formidable authoritarian institutionsto carry out his orders.Only a brave or self-destructivefew are willing to risk a confrontationwith Mahathir'sinfrastructuralpower by challenging his despotic power. The resilience of Mahathir'sregime during the crisis of 1998-99 representednot simply a triumphof individualwill, but also an impressive display of well-developed authoritarianinstitutions in synchronous motion. When Mahathir says "I actually work as a team,"he may be semantically incoherent,but he is substantivelycorrect. As opposition to his leadershipincreased, Mahathirdeployed an armada of institutions-the police, media, judiciary,bureaucracy,and party-to destroyhis chief rival and quell rising demandsfor political reformasi. The loyalty and compliance of these institutions were not evidently based on widespread affection for the prime minister. Rather,they appearedto be based primarily on the logic of obedience in a tightly defined institutionalhierarchy,in which top officials hold the effective capacity to recognize cooperation and defection and to rewardand punish them accordingly.Although a majorityof governmentofficials 83 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October2003 evinced dissatisfactionwith Mahathir'sstrong-fisted approach,they did not disobey his orders, as often happens when political institutions lack strongly established channels of hierarchicalcontrol.15Faced with dire consequences for noncompliance, the cogs in the party-statecontinuedobediently to work in their place. In sum, Mahathirhas used the mechanisms of packing, rigging, and circumventing to accumulate despotic power without significantly undermininghis regime's infrastructuralpower. Institutionsno longer fetter the executive, but they continueto choke off political opposition. To say that Mahathir'sregime is eitherpersonalizedor institutionalizedbut not both is to get only half the story right. In a regime with significant recourse to authoritariancontrols, the relationshipbetween despotic power and infrastructural power is positive-sum rather than zero-sum. Autocrats can monopolize despotic power without squandering infrastructural power, as in Malaysia from 1987 to 1997. Mahathir'sgrowing personalization of power during the recent political crisis was predicated on the strong backing he received from Malaysia's highly institutionalizedpolitical organizations.This institutionalframework is valuable for comparativeresearchon authoritarianinstitutionsand democratic transitions.High levels of infrastructuralpower not only foster a regime'spersonalization, but also appearto increase its resilience in the face of pressuresfor democratization. When underlying political organizations remain capable and coherent, authoritarianregimes can become more personalizedwithout becoming more brittle, contraryto theoreticalexpectationsthat personalizationmakes authoritarianregimes more vulnerableto collapse.16 Institutions in an Authoritarian Setting Unlike democracies, authoritarianregimes can be highly personalized and highly institutionalizedat the same time. A democracy that fails to curtail despotic decision-makingpower can not be called institutionalizedin any meaningfulway, but an authoritarianregime that lacks institutions for curtailing the executive might still exhibit powerful institutions for curtailing dissent. Before the positive-sumrelationship between personalizationand institutionalizationin authoritariansettings can be recognized or the causal impact of authoritarianinstitutions on democratictransitions determined,the critical distinction between these two very differenttypes of institutionsmust be appreciated. Studies of political institutionalization typically encompass both despotic and infrastructuralpower, yet they fail to note that two distinct dimensions are being measured. For instance, BarbaraGeddes defines an authoritarianregime as being institutionalizedundera ruling party,ratherthan personalized,if "the partyhas some influence over policy, controls most access to political power and governmentjobs, 84 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater and has functioninglocal-level organizations."'7Autocraticpersonal rule is replaced by oligarchic party rule when the ruling party manages to impose constraintson the leader's despotic power and to extend its organizationaltentacles to the grass-roots level. Combining two distinct historical processes under a single concept, however, leaves little conceptual guidance in assessing regimes that have undergoneone without the other. Even if it can be safely assumed that such political procedures and organizationshave historicallybecome institutionalizedin tandem, it should not necessarily be assumed that they become deinstitutionalized in tandem as well. For example, in a regime such as the institutionalized single party regime Geddes describes, an aspiring autocratmight gradually usurp the ruling party's influence in making authoritativepolicy and personnel decisions. Could it be safely assumed that the party's"functioninglocal-level organizations"would cease to function effectively as a result? Evidence from Malaysia will show that Mahathir Mohamad has appropriatedeffective decision-makingpower from a ruling party that continues to bestride the Malaysian polity like an organizational colossus. Yet there is no adequate conceptual frameworkeven to describe regimes that become highly personalized along one dimension while remaininghighly institutionalizedalong another. Selection bias appearsto be the main culprit. Most studies of institutionalization focus on cases where either weak political organizationsare correlatedwith personalized decision making, or strong political organizations coincide with routinized decision-makingprocedures.Studies of personal rule have derived mostly from subSaharanAfrica, where states have indeed tended to lack infrastructuralpower.I8 TheAfricanAutocratfaces limitationson his rule,butthey are the limitationsof resourcesand organizational capability-notof discretionary power.His poweris limitedby the relative"underdevelopment"of the ruling apparatusavailable to him, by limited finances, personnel, equipment, technology,andmateriel,as well as by the limitedskillsandabilitiesof his officials.Buthis disis-in principle-unlimited.19 cretionary powerto directthisapparatus Why must an autocratwith such unlimited despotic power be saddled with such limited infrastructuralpower? Why must states with highly developed political organizations not be governed autocratically?The failure to distinguish between despotic and infrastructuralpower obscures how personalization and institutionalization might go hand in hand in authoritarianregimes. How should political scientists cope with this conceptual complexity? One solution is to drop capable political organizationsfrom the definition of institutionalization altogether and limit attention to the regularization of decision-making procedures. Geddes ultimately chooses this parsimonious option, discarding her earlier approachand defining institutionalizationstrictly by how regimes make decisions, not by how they implementthem.20 85 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October2003 The problem with this approach is that the organized execution of leadership decisions is simply too importantto ignore, especially in an authoritariansetting. Among America'skey political institutions,a litany of proceduresis designed to curtail executive despotism: presidential term limits, advice and consent, judicial review, and federalism.But in authoritarianregimes (or unconsolidateddemocracies, for that matter),the most durableand consequentialinstitutionsare typically organizations. In Turkish,Indonesian,and Pakistanipolitics, for example, military forces, even when they are not playing a leading, day-to-daydecision-makingrole, are more importantthan the regimes' official decision-makingprocedures. It is thereforenecessary to incorporateboth despotic and infrastructural powerinto the institutionaltypology of authoritarianregimes. The most common institutional typology-military, single party, and personal-can capturehow despotic power is organized, since militaries, ruling parties, and individual leaders can all ostensibly make authoritativedecisions.21But it can not capturehow infrastructuralpower is organized,because personalrule says nothingaboutwhich organizationscarryout the leadership'sorders.To encapsulatethe key institutionsof any authoritarianregime, it is necessary not only to inquireabout who decides, but also about who executes.This approachgeneratesa new, four-parttypology (see Table 1).22This new typologymost obviously differs from other frameworks in excluding personal rule as a distinct regime type, while includingpersonalizationas a proceduralattributeof varyingforce in both party-backedand military-backedregimes. In a modem authoritarianregime, even a leader who enjoys significant charismaticor traditionallegitimacy must ultimately depend on his regime'sorganizationalapparatusto distributeselective rewards to loyalists and impose selective punishmentson rivals. To establish the analytic value of this new typology, however,it is criticalto show that these two types of institutionsdiverge not only conceptually,but also empirically. If high levels of infrastructuralpower always coincide with strong constraintson Table 1 InstitutionalTypologyof AuthoritarianRegimes ( (ho Executes?) ur hna Anum~ati Bossism Machine ____ 9(Who Milili j~~. DecidesIa)M11g Stroogman Junta . I Malaysia('9 ?-98), Singap re,'Vetnam,China(1976-present) Machn: Bojsis: Malaysia(1998-present)China(Mao),Kenya(Mot),Zimbabwe(Mugabe) Brazil(pre-19&) Korea (pre-1987). Burma,Thailand(r 1988),South (M= arraf), Nigeria(Abacha) (Mar )MPakistan Of Philippines SRD s: Indonesia;(Sh 86 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater despotic power,there is no reason to replace the existing tripartiteinstitutionaltypology with the four-partversion in Table 1. It will only have sacrificed parsimonywith no compensating increase in analytic power. In contemporary Malaysia powerful regime organizationshave not prevented the prime minister from monopolizing the effective power to make authoritativedecisions. To the contrary, the existence of such highly institutionalizedorganizationshas given MahathirMohamadthe institutional muscle he needs to keep political opposition in check. Mechanisms of Personalization How might an authoritarianruler usurp effective decision-making power from an institutionalizedcollectivity that put him in power?23Conventionaltheory holds that personalizationtends to occur in the early stages of a regime, before solid institutions take root.24It can grasp Lenin and Mao, who built loyal political organizations from scratch throughpersonal charisma,but not Stalin and Ceaugescu (or in a less totalitarianvein Mahathir,Moi, and Mubarak),who turnedinheritedorganizationsto their own purposes. Malaysia thus presents a serious theoreticalpuzzle, because it is a clear instance of postinstitutionalpersonalization. Its party system and state apparatushad been highly institutionalizedfor decades-both in the sense of oligarchic decision-making procedures and coherent, capable organizations-before Mahathir became prime minister in 1981. Michael Leigh neatly sums up the antecedent potency of Malaysia'sruling institutionsand their subsequentdominationby Mahathir. Probablythe most enduringconsequenceof the Mahathirerahas been a deliberateanddecisive weakening of Malaysia'sinstitutions,including the judiciary, the royalty,the independentcivil service, the parliament,the electoral system and now UMNO, the core party of power....The institu- tionsof governance aremuchweaker,andrulershiphasbeenpersonalized in a waythatis without precedence in Malaysia. Much of the past strength of Malaysia, by contrast with its neighbours, was in the enduranceof institutionsthat comfortablyaccommodatedchangesof leadersover time.25 Leigh is not the only Malaysia-basedscholar to conclude that Mahathir'siron fist has overpoweredMalaysia'spreexisting iron cage of political institutions. Ho Khai Leong argues that "the present office of the Prime Minister is a matrix of autocracy. The constitutionalprocesses and institutionsthat act as checks to prevent the Prime Minister from gaining dictatorialcontrol over the nation are incapable of functioning effectively."More specifically, "underthe Mahathiradministration,the Cabinetis no longer used as a forum, but ratheras a rubber-stampinstitutionthat gives legitimacy to governmentpolicies."26Khoo Boo Teik has similarly noted that there has been a centralization,"in some cases even a personalisation, of power...at the expense of 87 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October 2003 the independenceof key institutions."ChandraMuzaffarconcurs that the "most disastrous" aspect of Mahathir'stwenty years of rule has been "the emasculation of independentinstitutionslike the judiciary,the police, parliament,universitiesand the media."He adds: "That'sbeen the greattragedy of his rule-the overwhelmingdominance of one man."27 However, these scholars are simply arguing that despotic power has gone from highly constrainedto highly concentrated.Autocracy has displaced oligarchy.They are not arguing that the leadership is losing institutional control over active and potential opposition. It is thereforepartiallymisleading to say, as these observersdo, that institutionssuch as UMNO, the judiciary,and the media have been weakenedor emasculated. As democratic constraints on executive power, these institutions are indeed shadows of their former selves. But as authoritarianmechanisms for rewarding loyalty and punishing opposition to the regime, they remainrobust. Mahathirhas indeed managed to debase Malaysia's preexisting proceduresfor executive constraint,but not, as theory would predict, because they were especially weak to begin with. He has managed to personalize power because his institutionalized command over the party-state apparatushas permitted him to overpower or intimidate any individuals and institutionsthat stood in his way. One can not fully understandthe newfound weakness of Malaysia's institutions at fulfilling the core democratic function of curtailing the executive without first comprehendingtheir long-standing and continuing potency at fulfilling their core authoritarianfunction of curtailing political opposition. How can aspiring autocratspersonalize decisionmaking power in the face of preexisting procedural constraints? They have three mechanisms at their disposal: packing, rigging, and circumventing. Packing Packing is the appointmentof personal loyalists to top party and government posts while purgingrivals, therebyconvertinginstitutionalconstraintsinto institutional weapons. Authoritarianinstitutionalizationimplies not only high levels of commandand control within regime organizations,but also the extension and elaboration of these organizations to impose political control over society. Where such apparatusesof control predate a ruler's rise to power, an aspiring autocrat'sprime objective is to commandeerthem for his own purposes.This goal is most effectively accomplishedthroughthe packing of these organizationswith the ruler'sloyalists. With a wide array of proceduralprerogativesto make personnel appointments, Mahathirhas graduallymanagedto gain personal dominationover his regime'smost potent organizations.He began to undertakethis packing strategymost forcefully in 1987. As the result of a split within UMNO, TengkuRazaleigh nearly won control over Mahathir'spositions as the party'spresident and the nation's prime minister.In response, "Mahathirpurged his cabinet of Razaleigh's remaining supporters,who included three senior ministers and four deputy ministers, even though all of them had won party posts during the UMNO elections."28These purged leaders subse88 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater quently went to court to appeal Mahathir'snarrowvictory in the leadershipvote and their subsequentexpulsion from UMNO. "The Supreme Court rejectedthe appeal in August 1988, but not before Mahathirhad impairedthe independenceof the judiciary by securing the removal first of the Lord President, Salleh Abbas, on the grounds of judicial misconduct, and then of five Supreme Court judges who had risen to Salleh's defense."29 In short, to help him pack the cabinet and UMNO's supreme council, Mahathir needed to pack the judiciary. The effects have been significant. "Before 1987, we had a very good legal system,"notes one political analyst. "Now you see judges driving around in big Mercedes with tinted windows and 'Hakim Negara' (Federal Mahathirhas thus used the Judge) in big letters. They all belong to Mahathirnow."30o to the transform from one of the more respectMalaysian strategy packing judiciary ed and independentlegal bodies in Asia into a powerful fist at the end of his executive arm. Ratherthan curtail Mahathir'sdespotic power, the judiciary now primarily serves to enhancehis regime's infrastructuralpower. Mahathiralso responded to the crisis by packing the most importantpost in the cabinet with his most trustworthyloyalist of all: himself. From the UMNO split in 1987 until after the sacking of Anwar Ibrahimin 1998, Mahathirretainedthe portfolio of home minister, thus grantinghimself effective control over the real muscle in Malaysia'sparty-state,the police. Mahathir'spersonal stranglehold over this highly effective and repressive police force was a major reason why social pressures for political reform were snuffed out after Anwar Ibrahim's removal from office in September 1998. For now, the key point is that packing allows a leader to personalize decision-making authority without necessarily weakening the capacity of the organizations in question to execute his commands. Indeed, the more well-established the institutionis, the greaterare the chances its cogs will remain fixed regardless of who is guiding the mechanism. Rigging Rigging is the strategicmodification of institutionalrules and procedures to forestall competition for leadershippositions. Packing provides an ideal mechanism for denying challengers access to the organizationalbases of regime strength, but it has no direct effect on the proceduresthrough which the leadershipmight be challenged. In Malaysia, the only road to power leads directly throughUMNO, the ruling party. Since the party and state apparatuseshave become tightly intertwined over more than forty years of single party hegemony, whoever controls UMNO effectively controls the state. Historically,UMNO has been notable for its democratic intrapartycompetition, even as it acted in highly authoritarianways in the wider polity. Having nearly been toppled by such democratic intrapartycompetition in 1987, Mahathirused his dominance of the packed UMNO supreme council to systematically rig UMNO's internal election procedures. In short, "Mahathirremade UMNO itself. He changed the party's constitution to make it difficult to challenge 89 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October2003 incumbents. Mahathir,who stands for re-election every three years, has ever since run unopposed."31 This rigging of UMNO proceduresgatheredpace in the mid 1990s, as Mahathir increasingly feared a possible leadership challenge from his popular deputy,Anwar Ibrahim.While Anwar enjoyed substantialgrass-rootssupportwithin UMNO, he had difficulty gaining a foothold in UMNO's supreme council and the cabinet. Yet Mahathir'sdominance of UMNO in the supreme council and cabinet could not protect him from a floor vote at an UMNO general assembly meeting like the one Razaleigh'ssupporterscalled and nearlywon in 1987. Hence Mahathir'sneed for proceduralrigging. A detailed overview of the procedural changes has been provided elsewhere, but the basic rigging strategyis worth outlining briefly.32Mahathirintroducedan array of bonus votes, no contest resolutions, and bans on campaigning for top party posts to ensure both his and Anwar's continued incumbency as UMNO president and vice-president. IncludingAnwar in this protective net secured the supportof his faction for many of these resolutions, without permittingAnwar to resolve his deeper political problem, his lack of representation on the supreme council. When Mahathirchose to sack Anwar on unsubstantiatedcharges of sexual misconduct in 1998, he only needed the approvalof the supreme council, where his own loyalists had been effectively packed, and not the UMNO general assembly,where Anwar'ssupportmore closely rivaledMahathir's. UMNO procedures have clearly been rigged to facilitate Mahathir'spersonal domination of Malaysia's hegemonic political organization. But has UMNO lost organizational coherence or infrastructuralpower over society as a result? In the sense that UMNO lost substantialsupportin the 1999 general election, largely due to public outrage over Anwar'sdismissal and vilification, it has indeed been weakened. Yet it still utterly dominates the ruling coalition and still enjoys the kind of mass membership, territorialcomprehensiveness, and grass-roots intelligence network that it has developed over more than four decades in power. As unchallenged UMNO leader, Mahathiris the main beneficiary of "the party'sformidableelectoral machinery,"which "reachesdown to the smallest villages. UMNO stations one officer to monitor each 10 households in most ruralareas."33Mahathir'srigging of party proceduresmight have worn the machinerysome, but it has certainlynot eliminated UMNO's infrastructuralpower at the grass roots altogether. Circumventing Circumventingis the creation of alternativepolicy channels to divert influence and resources away from rivals in mainline governmentdepartments and toward loyalists in packed institutions.Any aspiring autocratis likely to enjoy more success at packing some regime organizationsthan others. When confronted with organizationsthat are too politically risky or intractableto pack, he can use the mechanism of circumventionas a fallback option. This approachaims to ensurethat authoritative channels for policy implementation and patronage distributionflow 90 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater through organizationscontrolled by the autocrat'sloyalists, ratherthan his rivals. In short, circumventionprivileges packed organizationsover unpackedones. Mahathirhas deployed such a strategyby systematically diverting decision-making authorityon nearly all majorpolicy issues to the prime minister'sdepartment,the most packed organization in the Malaysian government by definition and design. Under Mahathir's watch, the prime minister's department has evolved into the regime's nerve center for distributingpayments to loyalists and delivering punishments to rivals. Specifically, Mahathirhas circumventedmainline economic departments like the finance ministry-controlled from 1993 to 1998 by Anwar Ibrahimto manage Malaysia'sprivatizationagenda throughthe prime minister's department. Since privatizationhas been "the major form of patronageduringthe 1990s" for the UMNO-led regime, Mahathir'sdirect control over this process has been fundamental in his seizure of personalizeddecision-makingauthority.34 Might this type of deinstitutionalizationof decision-making procedurestranslate into the deinstitutionalizationof decision-executing organizations?While the packing and rigging of institutions has no clear negative effect on an authoritarian regime's infrastructuralpower, it is trickier to assess the possible impact of circumvention. Packing implies commandeeringthe power of an existing institutionfor personal purposes; circumventioneither requiresthe creation of entirely new organizations or requiresexisting organizationsto take on entirely new tasks. Circumvention thus implies the squanderingof at least a portion of a regime's institutionalinheritance. The big question is whether such institutional fraying can be expected to increase the chances of a regime's collapse and subsequentpolitical transition. Bossism in Bloom "Bureaucracyhas been and is a power instrumentof the first order-for the one who controls the bureaucratic apparatus."35Mahathir Mohamad exerted increasingly autocraticcontrol over the Malaysianpolitical system by the mid 1990s. Key events during Malaysia's dual political and economic crises of 1997-99 provide even stronger evidence that Mahathirmanaged to personalize decision-making authority and to do so by turningthe UMNO party-state'spowerful authoritarianinstitutionsto his personal advantage. Mahathir'sregime proved easily capable of surviving the financial and political crisis, in spite of its growing personalization. The regime hung together rather than breaking apart. Specifically, it hung together behind Mahathir'sstrategy of resolving the crisis primarilythrough repression ratherthan accommodationof dissent. The absolute loyalty of the police and other institutions of political control to Mahathirmade the regime more effective ratherthan less in foreclosing opportunitiesfor resistance. It not only made the regime more personalized, but also forestalledany prospect for a transitionto a more democraticorder. 91 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October2003 By 1997 only Mahathir'sdeputy, Anwar Ibrahim, still presented a check on his political preeminence. Mahathir'sposition suddenly became more tenuous, however, when the Asian financial crisis spread from Thailandto its SoutheastAsian neighbors. As the Malaysian ringgit and stock market plumbed new depths, Mahathir feared that he would be unable to rescue his political supportersin the corporatesector, who were suddenly buried under unserviceable mountains of privatedebt. This personal corporate clientele had been cultivatedthroughoutthe 1990s by an extensive privatization program, managed through the prime minister's departmentby Mahathirand his long-time associate, Daim Zainuddin.Mahathirwanted to ensure that he and Daim, and not Anwar, would make the final decisions on which corporate figures received state assistance. But Anwar was still perched atop the finance ministry and seemed more concerned than Mahathirabout the restorationof foreign investorconfidence, even if it meant letting some well-connected businessmenfail. To ensure uninterruptedpersonal control over the distributionof state resources, Mahathir deployed a circumvention maneuver, creating an ad hoc National Economic Action Council to counter Anwar's finance ministry.As always, this circumvention entailed the privileging of an ally as well as the weakening of a rival, as Daim, Malaysia's "virtual finance minister,"was appointed to lead the council.36 Mahathiralso used his direct control over a variety of discretionaryfundsto prepare strategic bailouts for key allies in the corporate sector. These assets included the national pensions fund, a savings account for Muslim pilgrims to Mecca, and, most important, the national oil company, Petronas, which also falls directly under the Malaysian prime minister's control. With an estimated $25 billion in cash as of November 1998, Petronas had more reserves on hand than the Malaysian central bank.37 By circumventing the finance ministry, Mahathirwas sending Anwar a strong message not to intervene in his bailouts of leading corporatefigures. But in March 1998 Anwar insisted on an independent audit of a Petronas-funded rescue of Konsortium Perkapalan Berhad (KPB), a heavily indebted shipping concern. Anwar's intervention was particularlybold because the bailout aimed to use $420 million in Petronas funds to wipe out the private debts of KPB's chief executive, Mirzan Mahathir,the prime minister's oldest son. When the bailout went through, one UMNO official lamented:"I thoughtsuch things could only happenin Indonesia or some African country."38 Once Anwar's objection to the Petronas-Mirzan bailout made his loyalty to Mahathir suspect, the prime minister stepped up his strategy of circumventing Anwar's finance ministry by diverting authorityto ad hoc, packed executive agencies. In June 1998 Mahathircreated a special cabinet post for Daim, ministerof special functions underthe aegis of the prime minister'sdepartment.On economic policy Mahathir'spacking and circumventingtactics had redirectedday-to-daydecision92 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater making power from his chief rival to the hands of his chief loyalist. He thus maintained a tight grip on the institutionalcircuits throughwhich patronageflowed. Politically, Mahathir'sefforts to weaken Anwar gathered steam as well. In July 1998, just six weeks before Anwar's eventual sacking, Mahathir engineered the replacementof the editors-in-chiefof two of Malaysia'sleading newspapers,as well as the director of operations at one of Malaysia's top television stations. All were reportedly close to Anwar. This replacement of rivals with loyalists in the mainstreammedia qualifies as an instance of packing a regime organization,because the press in Malaysia is far from independentof the government.The Malaysian press can best be thought of as the main propagandaapparatusfor the UMNO party-state or as a semiprivatizedappendage of the information ministry. All the mainstream papers are owned by corporateproxies for UMNO and its coalition partners,and the home minister has carte blanche to ban or curtail independentmedia outlets under the Printingand PublicationsAct. Said one of Anwar'sassociates in response to the dismissal of his top supportersin the press: "Their removal is the biggest setback Anwarhas had since he became deputy PM."39 With Anwar's allies in the press removed, Mahathirhad a free hand to destroy Anwar througha Blitzkrieg-likecampaign of characterassassination.As home minister and overseerof the police, Mahathirannouncedin September 1998 that Anwar would be sacked due to homosexual conduct discovered by the police's special branch investigativeunit. A special meeting of the UMNO supreme council promptly executed the prime minister'scommand.As Anwar himself described the session: "The president of the party opened the meeting by suggesting that I have to be expelled from the party before giving me the floor. What do you expect the supreme council membersto do? If they disagree, they will be expelled too."40 Once Anwar was officially removed,Mahathirpacked and rigged Malaysia'seconomic policymaking institutionsto limit the financial fallout. Realizing thatAnwar's dismissal would cause a collapse in investor confidence, Mahathirannounced new capital controls, thus preventing foreign investors from speculating against the Malaysianringgit or repatriatingfunds from the sale of their Malaysian stocks. With this breathingspace, Mahathirmoved to force down interest rates to ease the debt burden on well-connected companies. Since lending rates are officially determined in Malaysia by an independentcentral bank, Mahathirreplaced the market-friendly bank governor with the director-generalof the economic planning unit, the main economic arm of the prime minister'sdepartment. Mahathirthen not merely packed Anwar's former posts with loyal deputies, but took over some himself. For months after Anwar's dismissal Mahathiradded to his posts as prime minister and home minister Anwar's duties as finance minister. Mahathiralso effectively named himself deputy prime minister by refusing to name a replacementfor Anwar, thus putting Malaysia in danger of a succession crisis for 93 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October2003 the first time in its history. "Whathappens if the PM dies or falls sick?" asked one senior UMNO official. "It's irresponsiblenot to have a successor. It could result in political instability."41 In response to such criticism, Mahathirbrazenly displayed his autocraticcolors. After announcingto UMNO's supremecouncil that he would not name a new deputy as promised,over one month afterAnwar'ssacking, he declared:"It is not within the jurisdictionof the supremecouncil. It is my right to appointa deputy primeminister, what are his qualificationsand so on. I don't have to refer to anybody on this matter. That is my prerogative."42Mahathir's packed cabinet put up no resistance. One senior minister bluntly confirmed Mahathir'sabsolute discretionto sack Anwarunilaterally and to prevent the party elite from collectively selecting a new vice-president: "As the chief executive, the Prime Ministerhas 100% authorityto hire and fire and we are there at his pleasure."43 Having seized all the main institutionalreins of the regime, Mahathirmobilized a phalanx of regime organizations-the media, the police, the judiciary, and the UMNO-dominated bureaucracy-to prevent Anwar and his supportersfrom challenging his leadership. Despite Anwar's popularity, knowledgeable observers of Malaysianpolitics knew he had little chance against Malaysia'sformidablepolitical institutions."Anwarhas no political space outside,"said ShamsulA. B. "That'swhy he has not raised his voice against UMNO. He knows the only way he can come Jomo K. S. agreed: "Anwaris popularon the back to politics is throughthe party."44 ground, but organizationally he is weak."45And Singapore's senior minister Lee KuanYew-a man quite familiarwith the paramountimportanceof powerfulauthoritarian institutions-expressed confidence that Mahathirwould prevail. "I am prepared to wager five to one. I am not saying Anwar Ibrahimhas not got a following. What I am saying is that there are institutionalchecks and balances and systems that will not allow civil orderto be upset."46 These systems of control included the progovernmentmedia, which began a onesided campaign of characterassassinationagainst Anwar,presentingthe accusations against the fallen heir apparentas fact. Given the ownership structureof the media and the home minister'sprerogativeto rescind publicationlicenses at will, Mahathir could be confident that the press would not stray too far from the official line. Multiple independent publications have indeed been banned since 1998, and the main opposition party has seen its permission to print its own newspaperreduced from two issues per week to two issues per month. The Anwar affair also made Mahathir'spersonal dominationof the nation'spolice force perfectly plain. As home minister, Mahathirclaimed that police investigators had been telling him about Anwar's sexual misconduct for years, but since he had not initially believed the allegations, charges had never been pressed. In this clumsy attempt to appear magnanimous,Mahathirinadvertentlyadmitted that his personal protectionwas sufficient to place any of his loyalists above the law. When the direc94 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater tor of the police's special branchwas called to testify at Anwar's trial on corruption charges stemming from the sexual allegations, he admittedthat the investigationinto Anwar'sprivate life, OperationSolid Grip, had been terminatedin August 1997. At that time, Mahathirhad been quoted in the local press as saying that the rumors of Anwar'ssexual misconduct were "slanderous,politically motivated,"and "too absurd to believe." The special branch officer made his rationale for initially ceasing the criminal investigation perfectly clear: "We have to respect the decision of the PM and that was the reason why I did not propose to scrutinisethe case."47 Yet the Malaysianpolice also provide the clearest evidence that personal domination over the decision-makingproceduresin an authoritarianregime does not necessarily imply a lack of capacity in a regime's organizationsfor political control. To the contrary,the Malaysianpolice's institutionalizedloyalty to the prime ministerhelped ensure its coherence and effectiveness in suppressing both the elite defection and populardissent that inevitably arose when the most popularpolitician in the country was summarily dismissed and disgraced. Violent crackdowns on peaceful demonstrations quickly become the norm, and detention of Mahathir'sopponents (including Anwar sympathizerswithin UMNO) under the Internal Security Act became so routine that the KamuntingPrison for detainees became colloquially known as the "MahathirMarriott."48The infamous image of Anwar's black eye, courtesy of a severe police beating in solitary confinement while being held under the Internal Security Act, serves as ample testimony to the tactics Malaysian police use against perceived enemies of Mahathir'sregime. After a reportby Malaysia'sstate-appointed human rights commission criticized the police for their violent suppression of the reformasimovement,Mahathirappointeda new humanrights commissioner,the former attorney-generalwho had helped him impeach six justices and pack the judiciary in 1988.49 While the police followed Mahathir's orders and maintained stability on the streets, Malaysia's packed judiciary carried out Mahathir'spolitical death sentence againstAnwar in the courts. Two trials on corruptionand sexual misconduct charges duly delivered a combined sentence of fifteen years in prison for Anwar, in spite of disturbingirregularitiesin the trials' proceedings. The only people to admit having illicit sexual relations with Anwar did so while being held in solitary confinement under the InternalSecurityAct, and each later retractedhis confessions and detailed the police's physical and psychological abuse. When Anwar's lawyers noticed that the condominiumwhere Anwar was alleged to have performed these trysts had not even been built when the trysts allegedly took place, the trialjudge allowed the prosecution to alter the dates on the indictment.50Mahathirhas since rewardedthe attorney-general who prosecutedthe Anwar case with a seat on the supremecourt. Malaysia'spotent party-stateorganizationswere then deployed to ensure that the opposition would have no chance of removing Mahathir from office through 95 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October 2003 Malaysia's "competitiveauthoritarian"institutions. By holding elections before the end of 1999, the regime claimed the right to leave all 680,000 voters registeredin that calendaryear off the electoral rolls, recognizing that the lion's shareof new voters would side with the opposition if given the chance. UMNO wound up losing twenty seats in the election, in spite of a typically one-sided media campaign and unprecedentedreports of electoral fraud,including the widespread use of "phantom voters."51When a judge ruled that such electoral abuses in one district were so severe as to demand a revote, UMNO officials preparedto make futurecourt challenges to election results unconstitutional.52The judgment of the electoral commission-packed, unsurprisingly,with prime ministerialappointees-is heretoforeto be taken as the final word. In sum, Mahathirhas packed, rigged, and circumventedinstitutionsto purge and incarceratehis personal rival, suppress popular demands for political reform, steer the national economic producttowardhis most loyal supporters,and securethe electoral survival of his authoritarianregime. Authoritarianrule in Malaysiais more personalized, but no less resilient. Nevertheless, the days of Mahathir'sregime, like all personalizedregimes, are clearly numbered.Eventually,the septuagenarianwill have to exit the stage, either voluntarily or otherwise.53What arises in his place will depend to a great degree on how he leaves the scene.54 However, one theoretical point should be abundantlyclear: authoritarianregimes with coherent and capable party-stateorganizationsare structurallyvulnerableto processes of personalization, contrary to the common assumption that personalization feeds off of institutional weakness. The structuralopportunityfor future UMNO leaders to manipulateinstitutional means for personal ends, as Mahathirhas done, should not be underestimated. As long as control over UMNO continues to ensure control over Malaysia'shighly developed state apparatus,UMNO, in Weber'sterms, is a power instrumentof the first orderfor the one who controls UMNO. Summary and Implications Malaysia demonstratesseveral theoretical arguments.First, in Malaysia after 1998 authoritativedecisions derive from the will of an autocraticindividual,not the deliberations of an oligarchic collective. Malaysia challenges the assumptionthat personalization signifies weak institutionalization.In authoritarianregimes, personalization can arise amid strong institutionsas well as weak ones. Most important,Malaysiais noteworthyfor having had one of the most institutionalizedparty-statesin the developing world for decades before Mahathir began monopolizing decision-making authorityin the mid 1980s. Evidence from Malaysia also supportsa second theoreticalpoint: highly institutionalized authoritarianorganizationsfacilitate the personalizationof power.Leaders 96 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater like Mahathir,who was fortunateenough to inherit highly effective and disciplined party-stateorganizationsfrom his predecessors,enjoy personalpower of an altogether differentmagnitudethan leaders like Congo's LaurentKabila, who inherited only the institutionalruins bequeathedby Mobutu Sese Seko. In terms of decision-making procedures,both Mahathirand Kabila have presided over personalized regimes. But in terms of available, capable organizations to execute their commands, their regimes could hardly have been more different.When Mahathirneeded the support of Malaysia'sauthoritarianinstitutions in late 1998, they dutifully turned their considerable institutionalfirepower against Anwar Ibrahimand his supporters.By contrast,Kabila'spersonal guardturnedtheir firepoweragainst Kabila himself. Personalization amid strong organizations thus appears to have very different implications for authoritarian durability than personalization amid weak ones. Evidence from Malaysia strongly suggests that authoritarianregimes can become more personalized without becoming less resilient. To state this hypothesis even more boldly, variation in authoritarianregimes' infrastructuralpower is the key to explaining variationin their durability.Party-backedauthoritarianregimes appearto be exceptionally resilient because parties provide ideal organizationalmechanisms for the coordinatedexecution of decisions, not necessarily their collective formulation. They also appearto be systematicallymore likely than military-backedregimes to curtail and control dissent through the development of national organizations of political control.55 Thus, a different causal mechanism links authoritarianinstitutions to democratization than the one Geddes suggests. Her game-theoreticmodel imputes variations in regime durability from the bargaining incentives confronting different types of regimes in times of crisis. She ascribes the relative durability of party-backed regimes largely to the incentives party elites face under crisis conditions to unite, as tactical decision makers,behind a strategyof coopting potential opponents. Because the dominant strategy of the ruling coalition in single-partyregimes is to coopt potential opposition, single-partyregimes tend to respondto crisis by grantingmodest increases in meaningful political participation, increasing opposition representation in the legislature, and granting some oppositiondemandsfor institutional changes....Thisstrategyonly workssometimes,but it worksoftenenoughto extendtheaveragelifetimeof single-party regimes.56 This general explanation of single party durabilityis echoed by many Malaysians, who often explain the UMNO regime's durabilityas a result of its commitment to regular,semidemocraticelections that serve as a pressurevalve for political opposition. Ascribing the regime's resilience to its relative responsiveness would have been a hard argument to dispute before 1998, but this explanation sits less well with recent evidence. Malaysia'sparty-statedid not respond to the political crisis of 1998 by softening its stance towardits opponents, as Geddes would predict, but ratherby becoming increasingly authoritarian.Such state violence and repression might have 97 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October2003 sounded the death knell for a less organizationallycapable regime, but in Malaysia, where authoritarian organizations have a decades-long institutional memory, increased state repressionserved as a winning strategy.57 Nor does Malaysia appearto be an outlier in this regard.In the past severalyears alone, party-backedregimes that have loosened controls on the oppositionwhile permitting freer and fairer elections have been removed from office in Mexico, Taiwan, and Senegal. Meanwhile, party-backedregimes that have combined semicompetitive elections with continuing illiberal repression of the opposition have perseveredin such countries as Malaysia, Singapore, Cambodia, Zimbabwe, Kenya, Uzbekistan, Tunisia, and Egypt. Single party regimes might be particularlydurablebecause of the way they organize repression, not representation.This hypothesis gains further prima facie plausibility from those single party regimes that have completely eschewed the fagade of electoralismin the past decade. Cuba, China, Laos, Vietnam, and North Korea have proven surprisinglyresilient. In short, the world'sremaining single party regimes seem to sharea strongercommon commitmentto coercingtheir opponentsthan to coopting them.58Authoritarianregimes seem most likely to persevere when their institutionsexhibit sufficient infrastructuralpower to curtailopposition by punishing opponents and rewardingloyalists in pinpoint fashion. It seems less important whether authoritativedecisions represent the product of collective deliberationor individualwill. NOTES I wouldlike to thankJasonBrownlee,MichaelCoppedge,RickDoner,EdmundTerenceGomez,Walter Hatch,Allen Hicken,JomoK. S., RichardJoseph,BruceKnauft,Lee HockGuan,AndrewMacIntyre, DanReiter,BryanRitchie,RichardSnyder,RandyStrahan, KelleeTsai,andTuongVufortheircomments hasbeensupported andencouragement. Fieldwork Vernacular Modernities by the FordFoundation's proEducation. gramandtheInstituteforInternational 1. H. H. Gerthand C. WrightMills, FromMax Weber:Essays in Sociology(NewYork:Oxford UniversityPress,1946),p. 228. 2. ThomasFuller,"Malaysia Unrest:'WeArePrepared to HandleIt,"'International HeraldTribune, Sept.23, 1998. 3. Malaysiahasexhibitedanatypically"strong,centralized, directivegovernment" sincebeforeindeeversince.See pendencein 1957and"hasexperienced politicscharacterized continuity" by extraordinary RichardStubbs,"TheMalayanEmergency andthe Development of the Malaysian State,"in PaulB. Rich and RichardStubbs,eds., TheCounter-Insurgent State: GuerrillaWarfare and StateBuildingin the Twentieth andSociety Century(NewYork:St. Martin'sPress,1997),p. 67; HaroldCrouch,Government in Malaysia(Ithaca:CornellUniversityPress,1996),p. 32. 4. I defineauthoritarian regimesbroadly.Theyincludeany regimein which"incumbents routinely abusestateresources,denythe oppositionadequatemediacoverage,harassoppositioncandidatesand theirsupporters, andin somecasesmanipulate electoralresults."See StevenLevitskyandLucanA. Way, "TheRise of Competitive Journalof Democracy,13 (April2002), 52, andotherartiAuthoritarianism," cles in thisissueon "electionswithoutdemocracy." 98 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater 5. Mann defines despotic power in terms of the state's autonomy from civil society. I extend Mann's concept beyond power relationshipsbetween state and society to those within the state itself. See Michael Mann, States, War,and Capitalism:Studies in Political Sociology (Oxford:Basil Blackwell, 1988), p. 5. 6. Jennifer Gandhi and Adam Przeworski, "Dictatorial Institutions and the Survival of Dictators," paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, August 2001; Lisa Wedeen,Ambiguitiesof Domination: Politics, Rhetoric, and Symbols in Contemporary Syria (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1999); Gregory Kasza, The Conscription Society: AdministeredMass Organizations(New Haven:Yale University Press, 1995). 7. This term is also Mann's. It refers to "the capacity of the state to actually penetrate civil society, and to implementlogistically political decisions throughoutthe realm."Mann, p. 5. Yet a regime can overcome societal resistance only if it has first generated compliance within the state apparatus.I therefore include the organizationalcoherence of state institutionsin my definition of infrastructuralpower. 8. As Michael Coppedge has suggested, "this phenomenon is not unknown, but it is untheorized." Discussant's comment at the American Political Science Association annual conference, San Francisco, August 30, 2001. 9. A single case can strongly impugn a hypothesis by showing that it fails to hold where it should be most expected to hold. See Harry Eckstein, "Case Study and Theory in Political Science," in Fred Greenstein and Nelson Polsby, eds., Handbook of Political Science, vol. 7 (Reading: Addison-Wesley, 1975). 10. While UMNO rules througha multiethnic coalition, the Barisan Nasional (BN) or National Front, its position within the coalition is so hegemonic that Malaysia is essentially a single party regime. To simplify matterssomewhatfor nonspecialists, I refer to UMNO ratherthan to the BN throughout. 11. William Case, "Malaysia's Resilient Pseudodemocracy," Journal of Democracy, 12 (January 2001), 43-57; Levitsky and Way,p. 51. 12. See ZakariaHaji Ahmad, "Malaysia:Quasi-Democracyin a Divided Society,"in Larry Diamond, Juan J. Linz, and Seymour MartinLipset, eds., Politics in Developing Countries, vol. 3 (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 1989); William Case, "Semi-Democracy in Malaysia: Withstandingthe Pressures for Regime Change," Pacific Affairs, 66 (Summer 1993), 183-205; Crouch, ch. 13; Gordon P. Means, "Soft Authoritarianismin Malaysia and Singapore,"Journal ofDemocracy, 7 (October 1996), 103-17. 13. Crouch,ch. 5. 14. Stubbstraces the Malaysianstate'simpressive coercive capacity to the British-led emergency operation against leftists from 1948 to 1960. "By the end of the Emergencythe Malayangovernmenthad built up a substantialand relatively efficient security apparatus.The police had become a sizeable organisation and the Special Branch had gained a deserved reputationas an intelligence-gatheringorganisation."See Stubbs, p. 67. This security apparatuscontinued to play an active role in curbing dissent during the interregnum between British rule and Mahathir'sascendancy to the prime ministry."Between 1960 and 1981, 3,102 people were detainedat one time or anotherunderthe ISA." See Crouch,p. 80. 15. Meredith Weiss, "WhatWill Become of Reformasi? Ethnicity and Changing Political Norms in Malaysia,"ContemporarySoutheastAsia, 21 (December 1999), 432, suggests that perhaps 80 percent of ethnic Malays in the civil service did not supportMahathir'shandling of the political crisis. 16. BarbaraGeddes, "WhatDo We Know About DemocratizationafterTwentyYears?,"Annual Review of Political Science, 2 (1999), 115-44; BarbaraGeddes, "AuthoritarianBreakdown:Empirical Test of a Game Theoretic Argument,"paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, September1999. 17. Geddes, "AuthoritarianBreakdown,"p. 16. For a definition of institutionalizationin unconsolidated democracies that mirrorsthis dual emphasis on proceduresand organizations,see Scott Mainwaring, "PartySystems in the ThirdWave,"Journal ofDemocracy, 9 (July 1998), 70. 18. The same can be said for non-African cases of sultanism and neopatrimonialism, such as the 99 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ComparativePolitics October2003 Philippines under Marcos, which have attractedmore theoretical attentionthan highly institutionalized authoritarianregimes such as Malaysia's. See H. E. Chehabi and Juan J. Linz, eds., SultanisticRegimes (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1998); Richard Snyder, "ExplainingTransitionsfrom NeopatrimonialDictatorships,"ComparativePolitics, 24 (July 1992), 379-99. 19. Robert H. Jackson and Carl G. Rosberg, Personal Rule in BlackAfrica: Prince, Autocrat,Prophet, Tyrant(Berkeley: University of CaliforniaPress, 1982), p. 78. 20. Geddes, "WhatDo We Know?,"pp. 121-22. 21. Geddes, "AuthoritarianBreakdown";Geddes, "WhatDo We Know?";Samuel P Huntington,The Third Wave:Democratization in the Late TwentiethCentury (Norman: University of Oklahoma Press, 1991); Paul Brooker,Non-DemocraticRegimes: Theory,Governmentand Politics (New York:St. Martin's Press, 2000). 22. Geddes, "AuthoritarianBreakdown,"operationalizesthe party-personal,party-military,and military-personal divides, which correspond to my machine-bossism, party-military,and junta-strongman divides. My typology mainly differs in arrangingher variablesalong two dimensions ratherthan one. My typology is more focused but less ambitious than Juan Linz and Alfred Stepan, Problems of Democratic Transitionand Consolidation:SouthernEurope, SouthAmerica, and Post-CommunistEurope(Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1996), which encompasses issues of regime ideology and the extent of regime domination,not just that domination'sinstitutionalform. 23. Chehabiand Linz, eds., pp. 34-37, recognize the tendency for authoritarianinstitutionsto "decay" as long-serving leaders turn "sultanistic,"but they do not discuss how institutions might be actively destroyedratherthan passively "decay,"as dictatorsmanipulatecertain institutionsto destroyothers. 24. Samuel P Huntington,"Social and InstitutionalDynamics of One-Party Systems," in Samuel P. Huntington and Clement H. Moore, eds., AuthoritarianPolitics in Modern Society: The Dynamics of Established One-Party Systems (New York: Basic Books, 1970), p. 7; Geddes, "Authoritarian Breakdown,"p. 6; and Mainwaring,p. 69. 25. Michael Leigh, "Malaysia: 1961 and 2001," paper presented at the annual conference of the Association for Asian Studies, Chicago, March2001, p. 7. 26. Ho Khai Leong, "Aggrandizementof Prime Minister'sPower:The Transformationof the Office of the Prime Ministerin Malaysia,"InternationalesAsienforum,23 (1992), 243, 236. 27. Both quoted in Simon Martin, "MahathirStill Firmly in Control on 20th Anniversary,"AgenceFrance Press, July 15, 2001. 28. EdmundTerenceGomez, Political Business: CorporateInvolvementof Malaysian Political Parties (Kuala Lumpur:Vinlin Press, 1994), p. 62. 29. Ibid., p. 63. 30. Confidential interview,KualaLumpur,1998. 31. Jim Ericksonand Assif Shameen,"MountingPressure,"Asiaweek, Mar.27, 1998. 32. William Case, "The 1996 UMNO Party Election: 'Two for the Show,"' Pacific Affairs, 70 (Fall 1997), 393-411; Hari Singh, "Tradition, UMNO and Political Succession in Malaysia," Third World Quarterly,19 (April 1997), 241-54. Far Eastern Economic Review,Nov. 25, 1999. 33. Simon Elegantand S. Jayasankaran,"Juggernaut," 34. Case, "The 1996 UMNO PartyElection,"p. 399. 35. Max Weber,in Gerthand Mills, p. 228. 36. Ericksonand Shameen. 37. Choong Tet Sieu and ArjunaRanawana,"Filling Up at Petronas,"Asiaweek,Nov. 13, 1998. 38. "The Bailout Business,"Asiaweek, Mar.27, 1998. 39. Assif Shameenand ZoherAbdoolcarim,"Fadingfrom the Picture?,"Asiaweek,Aug. 21, 1998. 40. Eddie Toh, "Anwar Not Ruling Out Switching to Opposition Party PAS," Business Times (Singapore), Sept. 5, 1998. 100 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Dan Slater 41. S. Jayasankaranand MurrayHiebert, "The Ringmaster,"Far Eastern Economic Review, Oct. 15, 1998. 42. "LeftVacant,"TheStar, Oct. 7, 1998. 43. Charles Chan, "A Case of Swollen Ego, Says Rafidah", The Star, Sept. 16, 1998. This unconditional supportcame from a ministerwho has repeatedlylost grass-rootselections for the top women's post in UMNO, only to be resurrectedby Mahathir'sdiscretionaryoffers of seats in the cabinet and supreme council. 44. Choong Tet Sieu andArjunaRanawana,"A Case of Orderand Disorder,"Asiaweek, Oct. 16, 1998. 45. Ibid. 46. "Crackdown,"Asiaweek, Oct. 2, 1998. 47. Eddie Toh, "ProbeStoppedafter PM's Statement,"Business Times(Singapore),Nov. 10, 1998. 48. Anthony Spaeth, "He'sthe Boss," TimeInternational, Sept. 14, 1998. 49. K. Kabilan,"Police Responsible for Rights Abuses: Suhakam,"Malaysiakini,Aug. 20, 2001. 50. For a complete transcriptof the trial, see TheAnwar IbrahimJudgment(Kuala Lumpur:Malayan Law Journal, 1999). 51. See MeredithWeiss, "The 1999 Malaysian General Elections: Issues, Insults, and Irregularities," paperpresentedat the Annual Meeting of the Association for Asian Studies, San Diego, March2000. 52. K. Kabilan and Ng Boon Hooi, "Electoral Roll Amendment a Danger to Citizens Rights," Malaysiakini,July 20, 2001. 53. As one Malaysiancolumnist suggested to me: "The only way this man is leaving office is horizontally."Confidentialinterview,KualaLumpur,July 2001. 54. It is too soon to tell whether Mahathirwill make good on his recent promise (delivered in June 2002) to step down in October2003. More certain is that the decision will be Mahathir'sto make. 55. Malaysia has not taken the totalitarianroute of mobilizing functional groups into "administered mass organizations."See Kasza, esp. ch. 1. But given the national power and presence of UMNO, the federal police, and state organizationsin general, such extreme measures have hardly proven necessary to keep opposition in check. 56. Geddes, "AuthoritarianBreakdown,"pp. 16-17. 57. As the inspector-generalof police put it when the reformasi protests startedto swell: "From our experience in the '50s and '60s, we know what we are dealing with...." "Police OutlawAll 'Reformation Meetings,"' TheStar, Sept. 23, 1998. 58. Focusing on authoritarianinstitutions as instrumentsof cooptation is important,but incomplete. Gandhi and Przeworski,p. 3. Authoritarianregimes need strong institutions to serve as instruments of coercion as well. 101 This content downloaded from 212.175.32.134 on Wed, 31 Jul 2013 09:47:12 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions This article was downloaded by: [Koc University] On: 31 July 2013, At: 06:48 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Asian Journal of Political Science Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rasi20 Democratisation in Indonesia: From Transition to Consolidation Louay Abdulbaki Published online: 23 Jul 2008. To cite this article: Louay Abdulbaki (2008) Democratisation in Indonesia: From Transition to Consolidation , Asian Journal of Political Science, 16:2, 151-172, DOI: 10.1080/02185370802204099 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/02185370802204099 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/termsand-conditions Asian Journal of Political Science Vol. 16, No. 2, August 2008, pp. 151172 Democratisation in Indonesia: From Transition to Consolidation Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Louay Abdulbaki Despite many pessimistic expectations, the democratisation process in Indonesia has been progressing steadily over the past decade. The Indonesian political elite has crafted and stabilised a political transition mainly characterised by frequent, free and fair elections, peaceful rotations of power, effective elected officials and separation of powers, inclusive suffrage, freedom of expression, independence of the media and associational autonomy. In other words, within one decade, Indonesia has developed the main attributes of a democratic country, according to most theories of procedural democracy. However, the extent to which Indonesian democracy has been consolidated and institutionalised is another issue, which requires close examination and assessment. Does the Indonesian democracy fulfil or approximate the criteria stipulated by theorists of democratic consolidation? This article investigates the extent to which Indonesia has managed to advance its democratic transition and evaluates the prospects and challenges of democratic consolidation. In general, the article asserts that despite the persistence of a number of shortcomings, the steady progress of the Indonesian democratisation process and the consistent commitment of the principal political actors to the democratic rules of the game will likely lead to more institutionalised, policy-driven party politics and a gradual democratic consolidation in the foreseeable future. Keywords: Indonesia; Democratisation; Democratic Consolidation; Political Reform Introduction The resignation of President Suharto from office on 21 May 1998 marked the end of four decades of authoritarian rule and the instigation of a transition to a democratic, multi-party political system in Indonesia. This democratic transition involved a series of liberalising constitutional amendments and legislative reforms, which fundamentally altered the political process and structure of state institutions. In the process, Louay Abdulbaki, PhD, is affiliated with the Asia Institute, University of Melbourne. Correspondence to: Louay Abdulbaki, Asia Institute, University of Melbourne, Melbourne, Victoria 3010, Australia. Email: l_a_baki@ hotmail.com ISSN 0218-5377 (print)/ISSN 1750-7812 (online) # 2008 Asian Journal of Political Science DOI: 10.1080/02185370802204099 Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 152 L. Abdulbaki Indonesia has successfully conducted two peaceful, free and fair general legislative elections in 1999 and 2004 and three peaceful rotations of presidential power: from B. J. Habibie (19981999) to Abdurrahman Wahid (19992001), Megawati Sukarnoputri (20012004) and Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono (2004present). The most recent president was directly elected by the people for the first time in Indonesia’s history after constitutional amendments abolished the role of the People’s Consultative Assembly (Majelis Permusyawaratan Rakyat [MPR]) in choosing Indonesia’s president. Although the Indonesian democratisation process has been progressing steadily, the quality of Indonesian democracy and the extent of its consolidation are still under serious consideration and heated discussion. While ‘only democracies can become consolidated democracies’ (Linz and Stepan, 1997: 15), has Indonesia completed its democratic transition, so that the analysis can be turned to focus on aspects of democratic consolidation? This article seeks to tackle this question and to provide an assessment of the consolidation of democracy in Indonesia. However, before proceeding with a discussion of Indonesia’s democratic transition and consolidation, the article first discusses some important theoretical issues about the concept of democracy and sets out a theoretical framework for the rest of the investigation. Democracy and Its Preconditions The predominance of democracy, in its various guises, as the most acceptable form of government, particularly after the demise of the socialist alternative, has been perceived by some scholars as the end of the history of political ideas (Fukuyama, 1992). However, despite this somewhat uncontested acceptance, democracy remains one of the most contested or ‘appraisive’ concepts in modern social sciences (Esposito and Voll, 1996: 184). Dahl, for instance, contends that ‘polyarchy’1 hardly transcended to a ‘higher’ stage of democracy anywhere (1971: 8), insisting elsewhere that since democracy ‘has meant different things to different people at different times and places’, it is questionable that we can ‘possibly agree on what it means today’ (1998: 34). The most crucial point in the debate about democracy revolves around the issue of whether democracy is primarily a substantive way of life or a set of procedural rules. Two broad variants of conceptualisation dominate most approaches to democracy in this regard: the ‘maximal’ conceptions that stipulate substantive or comprehensive views encompassing social and economic aspects as defining criteria, and the ‘minimal’ or procedural definitions that are mostly concerned with the process of institutional arrangements. The maximalists reject the tendency, especially by some students of comparative politics, to associate democracy with elections, arguing that elections, though necessary, are inadequate criteria for democracy. They insist that, in addition to their vulnerability to manipulation, elections ‘occur intermittently and only allow citizens to choose between the highly aggregated alternatives offered by political Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Asian Journal of Political Science 153 parties’ (Schmitter and Karl, 1991: 78; Schedler, 2002). Therefore, many of the scholars who take this line of argument prefer maximal or expansive definitions of democracy that emphasise broad substantive objectives and equate social and economic development with democratic institutions. Democracy, according to this conception, is ‘not simply about form or means; it is also about ends, which have to do with its inherent capacity to enhance development’ (Osaghae, 1995: 189). Whereas the maximalists reject procedural democracy on the ground that it fails to consider problems of social and economic inequalities, minimalists question the usefulness of the maximal definitions of democracy for empirical research. In fact, by combining substantive all-encompassing concepts, maximalists conceptualise a democratic ideal, the expectations of which transcend actual democratic experiences, depicting democracy as a panacea for all social ills. Huntington draws attention to the fact that ‘[s]erious problems of ambiguity and imprecision arise when democracy is defined in terms of either source of authority or purposes’ (1991: 6). He emphasises that democracies ‘have a common institutional core that establishes their identity’, concluding that ‘[f]uzzy norms do not yield useful analysis. Elections, open, free, and fair, are the essence of democracy’ (Huntington, 1991: 9). Most scholars and analysts of democratic transitions find procedural definitions of democracy more useful for empirical research because they allow the application of the concept in various new settings on the one hand, and facilitate the establishment of an identifiable line which marks the end of the transition to democracy on the other. According to the proponents of procedural democracy, who mostly follow the tradition of Schumpeter (1947) and Dahl (1998), democracy is basically a means that enables all citizens to participate in politics and effectively influence the outcome of the decision-making process. Schumpeter defines democracy as a method or an ‘institutional arrangement for arriving at political decisions in which individuals acquire the power to decide by means of a competitive struggle for the people’s vote’ (1947: 269). Dahl presents a concrete institutional structure, according to which the ‘minimal requirements’ for a large-scale democracy must include six political institutions: (1) Elected officials [who must enjoy constitutional control over the decisionmaking process]; (2) free, fair and frequent elections; (3) freedom of expression . . . including criticism of officials, the government, the regime, the socioeconomic order, and the prevailing ideology; (4) access to alternative sources of information [e.g., independent media]; (5) associational autonomy and (6) inclusive citizenship. (1998: 8586, italics original) In addition to adopting the above procedural criteria in evaluating the democratisation process in Indonesia, this article emphasises that in order for democracy to be considered consolidated or stable in a newly democratised country, it must meet several requirements. Most importantly, authoritarian legacies and undemocratic alternatives must be totally eliminated and the principal political actors must demonstrate an unequivocal commitment to the democratic process or ‘the 154 L. Abdulbaki uncertain interplay of the institutions’ (Przeworski, 1991: 26). In addition, the occurrence of more than one democratic rotation of power, the institutionalisation of democratic practices and the development of a majority of public support for upholding the democratic system are also necessary for democratic stability and for the prevention of democratic breakdown (Linz and Stepan, 1997; O’Donnell, 1992). These elements are further elaborated and discussed later in this article. Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Indonesia’s Democratic Transition: The Absence of Preconditions The sudden and unanticipated fall of Suharto in May 1998 was a decisive moment in Indonesia’s history. Multiple factors had contributed to this event. The devastating Asian Economic Crisis, which hit Indonesia hard, was considered by many observers as the primary factor behind the fall of Suharto’s regime (Schwarz, P., 1999). There is no doubt that the crisis, to say the least, was one of the important contributing factors that provided the impetus for many Indonesians to challenge the status quo and demand radical reforms. Failing to recover the falling rupiah and get the economy back on track, Suharto’s government submitted to the International Monetary Fund’s conditions, which included reductions in subsidies and curbs on favouritism, especially with regard to companies controlled by Suharto’s cronies. The failure of the New Order government to regain investors’ confidence in Indonesia’s economic reforms, especially after Suharto’s re-election by the MPR on 10 March 1998 triggered the reformasi (reform) movement, which started with a series of large, anti-government student-led, demonstrations that spread from Jogjakarta and Jakarta to many other cities, ultimately culminating in the fall of Suharto’s regime (Mietzner, 1999a, b). After the fall of Suharto, however, the role of the students was rendered marginal, and the reformasi movement became largely a top-down process of an elitecrafted political transition, as elaborated in the following section. Indonesia’s unexpectedly successful democratisation has indeed dispelled many myths and flawed assumptions that have previously influenced the literature on democratisation in developing and Muslim-majority countries. For example, one of these assumptions is that development and modernisation, a justification used by most authoritarian regimes to prevent rather than promote democratisation, is a ‘precondition’ of or conducive to democracy (Diamond, 1992; Lipset, 1994). Other theories that also largely lost their explanatory power stipulate that public democratic culture is a precondition which must precede the democratisation process in order for the democratic transition to proceed steadily and for democracy to take hold (Almond and Verba, 1963; Almond 1980). Modernisation and development theorists assert that increased degrees of economic prosperity, industrialisation, urbanisation and education promise enhanced levels of political participation and democratic development. They assert that economic development is a precondition for democratic transition and consolidation because it leads to social transformations, such as the growth of the middle class and literacy levels necessary for the promotion of political representation, participation Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Asian Journal of Political Science 155 and government accountability (Lipset, 1994). In Political Man, Lipset argues that the level of modernisation or development in a certain country determines its potential to become a democracy, concluding that ‘the more well-to-do a nation, the greater the chances that it will sustain democracy’ (1960: 31) Other more recent studies that have tested Lipset’s hypothesis claim to have found substantial confirming results. Thus, ‘the more well-to-do the people of a country, on average’, Diamond affirms, ‘the more likely they will favour, achieve, and maintain a democratic system for their country’ (1992: 468). Yet empirical evidence, as many studies concluded, has proved that the process of modernisation and rapid economic and social change can also ‘breed socioeconomic conflict and political instability’ (Abootalebi, 2000: 4; Huntington and Nelson, 1976). On the other hand, the extent to which cultural values and shared attitudes influence political change and behaviour has been the major concern of many political and social scientists. Many scholars emphasise that democratic political culture for example, negotiating, bargaining, accommodating and willingness for compromise is a precondition for successful democratic transition. Political orientations, they assert, are influenced by knowledge, feelings, judgements and opinions about political systems. Accordingly, the development of a new democratic system requires not only formal democratic institutions but also a coherent political culture of which ‘the norms and attitudes of ordinary citizens are subtler cultural components’ (Almond and Verba, 1963: 3; Almond 1980). Other studies also assert that without sound commitments to democracy amongst ordinary citizens, democratic transition and consolidation is highly unlikely (Chu et al., 2001). However, many other scholars insist that empirical investigation yields little support for the cultural hypothesis, rejecting cultural determinism or any hypothetical preconditions to democracy. Diamond argues: ‘There are no preconditions to democracy, other than willingness on the part of a nation’s elite to attempt to govern by democratic means’, insisting that ‘neither culture nor history nor poverty are insurmountable obstacles’ (2003: 2). Moreover, some political analysts have questioned the role of Islam in influencing Muslims’ conceptions of political legitimacy and democracy. Islamic political culture, they argue, is unfavourable to democratic values and principles (Lewis, 1994; Eickelman, 1997). Huntington, for example, argues that ‘political participation was historically an alien concept’ to Muslim societies (Huntington, 1984: 208, 1991). Huntington makes this sweeping generalisation without even investigating whether the countries that experienced successful democratic transitions had had long histories of political participation before proceeding with their democratic processes. Many studies, on the other hand, have been more attentive to Islamic traditions that promote tolerance and openness. These studies emphasise the rich diversity of Islamic manifestations, applications and conceptions ‘of the nature of the state, Islamic law, the status of women and minorities’ (Esposito, 1995: 237; Mernissi, 1992). Consequently, any reductive generalisation of cultural or Islamic influence on political behaviour in Muslim-majority states will be too simplistic because it would Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 156 L. Abdulbaki certainly fail to reflect the profound complexity and wide variation of the reality of political culture in Arab and Muslim countries. A closer look at actual political landscapes in Muslim countries reveals that the relationship between Islam and the state or the role of Islam in political life ranges ‘from subordination of the state to Islam . . . to political accommodation . . . to political inclusion of Islam . . . to toleration . . . to ignoring Islam . . . to direct confrontation’ (Abootalebi, 2000: 119). Consequently, it is plausibly argued that democratisation processes and democratic culture can develop simultaneously, or that political democracy begets democratic culture (Rose, 1997). Thus, elite-crafted democratisation can be successful regardless of whether or not a democratic culture precedes the establishment of democratic institutions and procedures (Schmitter and Karl, 1991). In fact, the case of Indonesia’s instant democratic transition prompted many observers to acknowledge the ‘missing’ prerequisites of democracy. Hence, the argument that Indonesia ‘displays very few of the traits that political scientists have identified as propitious for the development of democratic political systems’ has become widely acknowledged in the literature (Webber, 2005: 6; Uhlin, 2000; Tornquist, 2004). Many analysts agree that contrary to most modernisation theorists’ calculations, according to which ‘the steady economic growth under the Suharto regime should have’ led to democratic development, the Indonesian democratisation process was instigated by the economic crisis which ‘triggered the fall of the dictator’ (Uhlin, 2000: 2, 5; Tornquist, 2002, 2004). Furthermore, the cultural hypothesis also finds little support in the Indonesian democratisation experiment. Webber draws attention to the fact that not only did the Muslim majority in Indonesia not prevent democracy but more importantly, the two main Muslim mass organisations, the Nahdatul Ulama (NU) and Muhammadiyah, played an important role in facilitating rather than obstructing the democratisation process (Webber, 2005). The importance of the role played by Muslim mass organisations since the early stages of the Indonesian democratic transition is widely acknowledged by political observers. As early as 1998, Budiman warned that if Amien Rais, the former leader of Muhammadiyah, did not ‘stick to his former position, namely to ask Suharto to step down and to create a coalition with the other two mass organizations [NU and Indonesian Democratic Party (PDI)] the unification of the three biggest mass organizations is in limbo, together with the prospect of democracy’. What is really remarkable about Indonesia’s democratisation is that it developed in tandem with the process of Islamisation, which began to take place during the last decade of Suharto’s rule (Webber, 2005). Consequently, Indonesia’s democratisation, Hefner argues, ‘should make us certain: that the desire for democracy and civil decency is not civilizationally circumscribed’, as ‘[d]emocratic ideals are broadly appealing because they respond to circumstances and needs common across modern cultures’ (2000: 220221). In short, the Indonesian democratisation experiment has proven that the cultural hypothesis posited by some cultural relativists lacks explanatory power. Asian Journal of Political Science 157 Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Indonesian Democratic Craftsmanship: The Transitional Phase As mentioned earlier, after the fall of Suharto, the role of the student movement lacking an ideological cohesiveness, organisational base and unifying political leadership and agenda became increasingly marginal. Hence, although the students succeeded in attracting support and exerting pressure sufficient to force Suharto’s resignation, the leadership of the reformasi movement was transferred into the hands of a network of influential leaders, and the democratic transition henceforth mainly developed through political pacts amongst a group of Indonesian elite. Therefore, the Indonesian democratic transition took an ‘evolutionary’ path, which ‘was quite disappointing for the reformasi total agenda of the students’ (Budiman, 1999: 47). Prominent leaders, such as Amien Rais, Abdurrahman Wahid and Megawati Sukarnoputri, who formed with the Sultan of Jogjakarta the Ciganjur Group, played an important role in facilitating political reform and stabilising the democratic transition (Budiman, 1999: 4647; Falaakh, 2001). The most remarkable achievements gained during the transitional phase of Indonesian democratisation were primarily realised through a series of constitutional amendments, a number of new statutes and legislative revisions which governed the new political processes and restructured the state institutions. Thirtyone of the 37 articles of the 1945 constitution were somehow affected by the new constitutional amendments (MPR, 2002).2 These amendments and revisions particularly modified the structure of Indonesia’s representative and legislative institutions at the national, regional and local levels. They also removed restrictions on political participation, permitted the formation of new political parties and enhanced the electoral rules and processes. Other important reforms also included the guarantee of the freedom of expression, associational autonomy and the independence of the media. As such, after the fall of Suharto, the MPR emerged as a major player in the ensuing democratisation process. Most of all, it facilitated the peaceful rotation of presidential power three times before the introduction of direct presidential elections. It forced Suharto’s successor, President Habibie, to withdraw from the presidential race when it rejected his accountability speech on 19 October 1999 after the legislative elections. The MPR also managed to impeach President Wahid after he lost the support of most of his former allies, in favour of his vice-president, Megawatti Sukarnoputri. Consequently, the elimination of the possible re-emergence of a new presidential dictatorship was one of the most important achievements that allowed the democratic transition to maintain consistent and steady, though somewhat slow, progress. On the other hand, taking into account the pressures that brought Suharto down, President Habibie introduced new important measures that liberalised the political system and expressed his intention to call for premature free and fair elections in his attempt to present an image of a reformist leader. Remarkably, Habibie led a reform government which, by and large, managed to liberalise the Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 158 L. Abdulbaki political process at a time when the status quo and Suharto loyalist forces were still very strong and determined to prevent any meaningful reforms. Habibie’s government freed many political detainees, lifted restrictions on the media and managed to pass new laws on elections and political parties, ending Suharto’s threeparty system and opening up the field for free and fair electoral contests. Using his presidential power and utilising his political influence over the Golkar party, which then controlled both the People’s Representative Council or Indonesian Parliament (Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat [DPR]) and MPR, Habibie embarked on a cautious campaign against corruption, collusion and nepotism (korupsi, kolusi, nepotisme [KKN]). For example, within a few months, over 20% of the Suharto loyalist members of the MPR were replaced with pro-reformasi members, either by voluntary resignation or forced removal. About 229 both appointed and elected members of the Assembly, including seven of Suharto’s family members, were ousted from their seats in the MPR.3 Furthermore, as the number of MPR seats was reduced from 1,000 to 695, ‘the proportion of directly (66 per cent) or indirectly (29 per cent) elected representatives more than doubled, from 43 per cent to 95 per cent’ (King, 2003: 5556). In addition to the fact that the number of appointed military representatives (who were later eliminated, as will be shown) in the DPR was reduced from 75 to 38, military personnel were prohibited from taking positions in the bureaucracy while serving in the armed forces (Jakarta Post, 1999b). Reforms on election laws can be considered as the most important achievements of Habibie’s government, and certainly amongst the most important steps that facilitated Indonesia’s democratic transition. On 28 January 1999, the parliament passed three political laws that provided the legal basis for the 1999 elections. They included Law No. 2/1999 concerning political parties, Law No. 3/1999 concerning general elections and Law No. 4/1999 on the composition and membership of the MPR, DPR and Regional House of People’s Representatives (Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat Daerah [DPRDs]) (for the full texts see the MPR [1999]; for a detailed discussion, see Masters [1999]). The laws codified Habibie’s proposal to conduct the 1999 elections and decreed that political parties that meet the legal requirements should be able to contest elections freely. They also removed the provision for ideological uniformity (azas tunggal or sole basis) formerly imposed on political parties and social organisations. Accordingly, though still prohibited from adopting ideological platforms that contradict pancasila (five principles),4 political parties are no longer required to adopt pancasila as their sole basis. In addition, the 1999 election law provided for the establishment of an independent General Election Commission (Komisi Pemilihan Umum [KPU]), the membership of which would include representatives of political parties participating in the general elections and five government officials (Jakarta Post, 1999a). Despite some defects, the three political laws passed by the parliament provided a strong basis for a multi-party system and by and large, free and fair elections. Consequently, these political laws Asian Journal of Political Science 159 were broadly accepted by the major political parties and leaders who agreed to participate in the elections. Democratic Consolidation in Indonesia Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Before proceeding with the assessment of the extent to which Indonesian democracy has been consolidated, the completion of Indonesia’s democratic transition has to be addressed and verified. Linz and Stepan emphasise that the transition to democracy in a given country: is complete when sufficient agreement has been reached about political procedures to produce an elected government, when a government comes to power that is the direct result of a free and popular vote, when this government de facto has the authority to generate new policies, and when the executive, legislative and judicial power generated by the new democracy does not have to share power with other bodies de jure. (Linz and Stepan, 2001: 19) If we take these criteria as a benchmark, Indonesia today enjoys the main attributes of a democratic country. The political process in post-Suharto Indonesia, as the investigation above has demonstrated, has been predominantly characterised by the establishment of frequent, free and fair elections, effective elected officials, separation of powers, inclusive suffrage, freedom of expression, independence of the media and associational autonomy. Many observers, therefore, consider the 2004 parliamentary and direct presidential elections the start of the process of democratic consolidation where the democratic electoral process and peaceful alternation of power have become established practices. A few months before the 2004 elections, the Asia Foundation conducted an opinion poll in order to assess the political culture of the Indonesian electorate, concluding with the assertion ‘that democracy has begun to take root in Indonesia’ (Asia Foundation, 2003: 2728). Electoral credibility, according to the Asia Foundation’s report, was no longer a real concern at that stage, and the priority had to be redirected toward the promotion of democratic consolidation. Other scholars, such as Azra (2006), also consider the 2004 elections as the end of the transitional phase of Indonesian democracy. Hence, Indonesia’s democratic transition has been completed, at least from a procedural perspective. The extent to which Indonesian democracy has been consolidated and institutionalised, however, is another issue which requires some further elaboration and assessment. What are the main characteristics and ideal criteria of a consolidated democracy according to theorists of democratic consolidation? What do we find when we evaluate the degree to which Indonesian democracy fulfils or approximates the criteria stipulated by these theorists? Generally speaking, scholars of democratic consolidation have sought to develop, not without some confusion, specific criteria that help evaluate the degree to which the democratic process and practices in a given country are consolidated and 160 L. Abdulbaki institutionalised. According to Przeworski, democracy can be regarded as consolidated when it Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 becomes the only game in town, [where] no one can imagine action outside the democratic institutions all the loser wants to do is to try again within the same institutions under which they have just lost . . . all relevant political forces find it best to continue to submit their interests and values to the uncertain interplay of the institutions. (1991: 26) Two primary elements can be identified in these criteria: the elimination of all other alternatives that may compete with the democratic system, and the consistent commitment and unreserved submission of all important political actors to the democratic rules of the game, even when the outcome is not favourable to them. Schneider and Schmitter basically adopt similar criteria, but they also add the likelihood of developing ‘mutual trust and reassurance among the relevant actors’, where the process of ‘contingent consent’ becomes institutionalised, that is, an established or accepted part of the political structure (2004: 61). They also include the condition that one or more rotations of power should occur before consolidation is considered. Linz and Stepan, on the other hand, extend the notion of institutionalisation beyond the political and elite-behaviour domain, incorporating public attitude as an indicator of democratic consolidation. According to Linz and Stepan, democracy is consolidated: [W]hen a strong majority of public opinion, even in the midst of major economic problems and deep dissatisfaction with incumbents, holds the belief that democratic procedures and institutions are the most appropriate way to govern collective life, and when support for antisystem alternatives is quite small or is more or less isolated from prodemocratic forces. (Linz and Stepan, 1997: 16) However, despite its empirical usefulness, Linz and Stepan’s conception of a consolidated democracy includes several aspects that make the distinction between non-consolidated and consolidated democracies largely obscure. On the one hand, they disqualify regimes in which all violations of the rule of law or individual rights are not totally eliminated from the rank of democracies, even if they fulfil the ‘institutional requirements for [free and fair] elections in a polyarchy that Robert A. Dahl has set forth’ (Linz and Stepan, 1997: 1415). On the other hand, when they clarify some of the qualifications of consolidated democracies, they emphasise the persistent possibility of democratic breakdown, the existence of different (unspecified) types of consolidated democracies and the improvability of the quality of democracy in consolidated democracies, stipulating ‘a continuum from low-quality to high-quality democracies’ (Linz and Stepan, 1997: 16). The problem is that one finds it difficult to differentiate between a democracy that meets Linz and Stepan’s criteria and a consolidated democracy, especially of a low-quality kind. Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Asian Journal of Political Science 161 However, although ‘democratic consolidation’ remains a highly contested concept, it can still be utilised as a useful analytical tool for empirical research, especially with regard to the hypothetical projection of the likelihood or otherwise of the stability and continuity of newly established democracies. Therefore, regardless of the heavily disputed elements, several common constituents can be identified in the theories of democratic consolidation discussed above: most importantly, (1) the elimination of all authoritarian legacies and undemocratic alternatives, (2) the unequivocal and consistent commitment of all significant political actors to the democratic rules of the game, (3) the occurrence of at least one democratic rotation of power, (4) the routinisation and institutionalisation of democratic practices and procedures and (5) the development of a strong majority of public support for upholding the democratic system. In general, all these elements are basically concerned with democratic survival and the elimination or prevention of the possibility of democratic breakdown or ‘rapid death’ (O’Donnell, 1992: 17). Arguably, if these five elements persist in a newly established democracy, they will eventually lead to a deeper and higher-quality democracy. As the investigation in this article has shown, and judged against the above criteria, Indonesia today possesses most of the characteristics of a consolidated democracy, though some very important challenges still lie ahead, especially with regard to the deepening and institutionalisation of democratic practice. During the transitional phase of Indonesia’s democratisation, the pro-reform political actors were heavily involved in the process of eliminating the Suharto-era authoritarian legacies. As the New Order restrictions on political participation and freedoms were removed and the field for free and fair electoral contestation was opened, the new pro-democracy members of the 1999 parliament embarked upon a democratisation campaign in the face of an ailing pro-status quo elite. In one battle after another, the reform-minded leaders who were determined to complete and stabilise the democratic transition defeated the anti-democracy actors and forces of the status quo. With the total elimination of non-elected parliamentary members, especially with regard to the military’s reserved seats, Indonesia’s representative and legislative institutions became fully democratised. The military accepted the new rules of the game without significant resistance, and its role in politics has been substantially minimised, though it has not yet dismantled its territorial structure and business activities that are largely beyond the control of the government, as will be discussed later. All relevant social and political forces, Islamic and secular or winners and losers, have always accepted the outcomes of democratic elections and legislative deliberations. Islamic parties and forces that lost their bid to re-introduce the Jakarta Charter into the constitution accepted the outcome without any mass rejection. Mainstream Islamic political parties have been pursuing their ends by peaceful and democratic means. In short, democracy has become ‘the only game in town’, and all undemocratic alternatives have been by and large eliminated. With all significant political actors consistently showing unequivocal commitment to the democratic rules of the game, the threat of democratic breakdown or ‘rapid Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 162 L. Abdulbaki death’ has become increasingly unlikely. In fact, post-Suharto Indonesia did not see the emergence of any significant deviant or anti-democratic actors with access to substantial resources and support that could be invested in advocating antidemocratic activities and objectives. Even military-backed officials no longer seek to achieve their ends by the use of non-democratic or unconstitutional means. Furthermore, since the instigation of the democratic transition, Indonesia’s advancement toward the consolidation of its democracy has been buttressed by three peaceful rotations of power. The three presidential alternations occurred as the result of democratic votes in parliament for Abdurrahman Wahid (1999) and Megawati Sukarnoputri (2001) or of direct presidential elections for Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono (2004). The transition of presidential authority in each of these rotations was peaceful; even though the transition from Wahid to Sukarnoputri became tense when the former threatened to declare a state of emergency and dissolve the parliament, no significant political force rejected the outcomes. Consequently, with the constitutional balance of power between the legislative and executive branches of government and the highly successful implementation of democratic/constitutional government rotations, the possibility of the emergence of a presidential dictatorship has become highly unlikely, this being an essential element of democratic consolidation. However, one of the challenges that Indonesia has yet to fully address in order to join the rank of consolidated democracies is the ability to apply full ‘civilian control’ or ‘supremacy’ over the military (Agüero, 1997: 177). In fact, the extent to which the Indonesian military (Tentara Nasional Indonesia [TNI]) has been able to maintain its influence, formally or informally, over government policies is highly disputable. Historically, the TNI (formally Angkatan Bersenjata Republik Indonesia [ABRI]) has occupied a central position in political and social life, where under both Sukarno’s and Suharto’s regimes, it maintained its traditional dual political and military role. The military doctrine of dwi fungsi (dual function), which was laid down by the Chief of Staff Nasution in 1957 when he formulated the theory of a ‘middle road’, was used to legitimise the dominant role of the military in society (Koekebakker, 1994). Under Suharto’s New Order regime, military officers held key ministerial and bureaucratic positions, were allocated 20% of the seats in the legislature (this was later reduced) and were able to maintain control of local government through the use of its command structure, which is organised on a territorial basis throughout the entire country providing a parallel to governmental structures (Koekebakker, 1994). The military has maintained a web of commercial business ventures since 1957, when it took control of Dutch-owned enterprises. These commercial enterprises enable the TNI to sustain an independent financial system, which remains beyond government scrutiny or civil oversight (Rabasa and Haseman, 2002; Nurhasim, 2005). Whereas the official defence budget is traditionally estimated to cover less than 30% of the TNI’s operational expenses (more recent estimates place the figure at about 50%), in order to balance its budget, the TNI relies on ‘profits from its own businesses, payments from private-sector allies (often for security services), income from black Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Asian Journal of Political Science 163 market activities, and money skimmed from corrupt dealings’ (Human Rights Watch, 2006: 35; Greenlees, 2005; Chipman, 2006). This has become one of the most formidable obstacles which makes the consolidation of democracy in post-Suharto Indonesia take a considerably slow pace. In fact, the military’s financial autonomy, which remains outside government control, makes it harder for the ‘civil authorities to engage in meaningful oversight of the military’ (Human Rights Watch, 2006: 1). As a result, the government ‘lacks the power to demand accountability from its armed forces and to implement needed reforms’ (Human Rights Watch, 2006: 1). Under post-Suharto democratisation, many positive steps have been taken to promote the return of the military to the barracks and establish civilian supremacy and control over it, though serious challenges that somewhat hamper the progress of democratic consolidation still persist. After the fall of Suharto, the military quickly joined the reform efforts, re-considering its role in politics and revising its doctrine. Therefore, the TNI formally relinquished its dual function and withdrew from its political role. The new constitutional amendments have eliminated the military’s representation in the legislatures. Accordingly, since the 2004 elections, the military no longer holds appointed seats in parliament. The police force has also been separated from the military and removed from its control. Military officers are no longer allowed to occupy positions in the bureaucracy while still in service, and civilians have been appointed as ministers of defence. Most importantly, a new law mandating the end of the military’s economic activity and the transfer of its business holdings into the control of the Indonesian government within five years was introduced in 2004 (Paras Indonesia, 2007; Human Rights Watch, 2006). Although the 2004 military reform law which requires the TNI to limit its financial sources to the state’s budget has been hailed as a major step towards the full assertion of civilian control over the military, political observers are increasingly becoming sceptical about the prospects of its full implementation. While the formal stances of government officials and the military leadership have been positive towards the military reform agenda, efforts to dismantle the military’s business and its territorial structure have, to date, largely failed and progress has been highly selective, ‘slow, half-hearted, and incomplete’ (Paras Indonesia, 2007; Human Rights Watch, 2006). According to Indonesia’s Defence Minister, Juwono Sudarsono, out of 1,500 military enterprises, only six ‘qualify as businesses to be turned over to the government’ (Paras Indonesia, 2007). Consequently, although its dual-function doctrine has been formally relinquished, the military has been able to maintain its territorially based structure as well as a ‘dense web of military/business ties’ and activities that are largely beyond the control of the government, which ‘creates a parallel administrative structure to the government, allowing the army to act as a type of localized paramilitary police’ (Freedman, 2007: 205206). However, despite its slow pace, military reform seems to be progressing steadily. Many observers believe that the steady progress of civilmilitary reforms will eventually lead to the consignment of ‘the military to the barracks for good a critical Rubicon Indonesia needs to cross in its march to democratic consolidation’ Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 164 L. Abdulbaki (Juoro, 2006). In fact, taking into account the total elimination of the military’s reserved representation in parliament, the prohibition of military personnel from taking positions in the bureaucracy, as well as the removal of the military’s control over the police, the progress achieved so far seems to outweigh the remaining challenges. Some observers argue that with its consistent autonomous stance and support of the formal political process, ‘the military has contributed positively to the ongoing security reforms required to consolidate democracy in Indonesia’ (Barron et al., 2005: 34). With regard to the criteria of the institutionalisation of democratic practices and procedures, Indonesia’s democracy demonstrates elements of both strengths and weaknesses, though many researchers have put more emphasis on shortcomings in relation to this. It should be noted here that the institutionalisation of democracy is meant to describe a political environment in which the rules of the democratic game become ‘routinised’ as a natural part of everyday life, rather than a careful or conscious process of costbenefit political calculations on the part of the political actors. Political actors in this situation become habitually committed to the democratic process and customarily subjected to the rule of law (Linz and Stepan, 1996: 6). Several weaknesses were identified in this regard during the 2004 legislative elections, though the elections themselves were remarkably peaceful, well organised and, as mentioned above, are largely regarded as an important step towards the consolidation of democracy. Barron et al., for example, emphasise that the 2004 elections highlight serious ‘institutional weaknesses’ and demonstrate ‘a need for capacity-building, increased professionalism and broader social engagement on the part of state actors’, though they confirm that the elections were ‘generally positive’ and free and fair (2005: 23, 3233). The weakness of the institutionalisation of democratic practices can also be identified through the lack of party platforms in election campaigns, especially, but not exclusively, within the camp of Islamic parties. Almost all Indonesian political parties rely mainly on charismatic leadership rather than political programs and policies in order to attract the electoral vote. The Prosperous Justice Party (PKS) is the only notable exception. The removal of the restriction on the formation of political parties inspired the emergence of many new Islamic-oriented parties. These parties explicitly adopt Islam as their ideological basis, use Islamic symbols to attract the Muslim vote and/or rely heavily on Islamic social organisations for electoral support. About 21 out of 42 newly formed Islamic parties were amongst the 48 parties that met the legal requirements for participating in the 1999 legislative elections. This, in fact, prompted many observers to raise concerns and scepticism about the future of the democratic process and consolidation in Indonesia (Azra, 2006). Some observers, for example, began to question the role that Islamic parties would play in a fully inclusive multi-party system. Some people suggested that the prospects for democratisation would be bleak and that the Indonesian society would be prone toward intercommunal violence, even ‘among the Muslims themselves’ (Jamhari, 1999: 183). Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Asian Journal of Political Science 165 However, contrary to many pessimistic expectations, Muslim leaders and Islamic parties have played a constructive role in facilitating and stabilising Indonesia’s peaceful transition to democracy. Indonesian Islamic parties have participated in building political alliances, contested in elections in a peaceful democratic manner and always accepted the outcomes of parliamentary elections and legislative deliberations. With the exception of the United Development Party (Partai Persatuan Pembangunan [PPP]), which was one of the three Suharto-era political parties alongside Golkar and PDI-P (formerly the PDI), the newly formed popular Islamic parties were founded by former leaders and activists of Islamic social organisations and movements, such as the NU, Muhammadiyah, the Indonesian Council for Islamic Propagation (Dewan Dakwah Islamiyah Indonesia [DDII]) and Islamic student groups. Islamic parties rely heavily on these and other less prominent Islamic movements and organisations for their membership base and electoral support. Four of the eight most popular Indonesian parties in the 2004 elections were in fact Islamic oriented. Three of them were established in the post-Suharto era. They include the National Mandate Party (Partai Amanat Nasional [PAN]), the National Awakening Party (Partai Kebangkitan Bangsa [PKB]) and the Prosperous Justice Party (Partai Keadilan Sejahtera [PKS]). The latter deserves particular attention as it is the only Indonesian party which managed to obtain significant growth in the 2004 elections. Considering its impressive performance in social and anti-corruption activities and programs, the PKS will most likely increase its share of the vote and may even emerge as one of the two largest Islamic parties in the coming elections of 2009. PAN was established in 1998 by Amien Rais, with the assistance of a group of antiSuharto reform activists, after his few unsuccessful attempts to form a broad alliance with Islamic modernist organisations. Rais was viewed by many Indonesian and foreign observers as a leader ‘who could unite some of the more disparate elements of modernist politics’ (Fealy and Platzdasch, 2005: 7399). In his efforts to appeal to the broader national electorate and present an image of a liberal and pluralist leader, Rais included non-Muslims, especially Christian Chinese, in PAN’s leadership and promoted pluralism rather than adopting a formalist Islamic agenda (Budiman, 1999). PAN, as such, adopted Pancasila as its ideological basis. However, this does not represent an insensitivity to, or even subordination of, Islamic aspirations. Rather, as Rais himself asserted, it signifies the belief that the five principles do not contradict Islamic tenets (Schwarz, 1999). Islam remains the predominant characteristic of PAN, because it has been closely associated with, and dominated by, the modernist Muslim community, especially members of Muhammadiyah. This makes it more appropriately situated within the Islamic camp, and thus it should be included in the category of Islamic parties rather than the nationalist or secular camp (Schwarz, 1999; Diederich, 2002). The PKB, on the other hand, was founded in July 1998 by Abdurrahman Wahid’s loyalist members of the NU. PKB’s adoption of Pancasila as its official ideological basis largely reflects Wahid’s pluralist political and religious views. Despite the fact Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 166 L. Abdulbaki that the PKB aspires to be viewed as a non-sectarian party which welcomes nonIslamic elements within its leadership board and membership base, while predominantly dominated by NU members, it primarily represents the traditionalist Islamic community in Indonesia (Mietzner, 1999b; Jakarta Post, 2000). As such, like the modernist PAN, the PKB should also be included within the category of Islamic parties rather than in the secular nationalist camp. Both PAN and PKB rely on Muhammadiyah and NU, respectively, rather than on their political platforms, for their membership and electoral support and largely owe their popularity to the charismatic personalities of Rais and Wahid. The PKS was founded in July 1998 and contested the 1999 elections under the name Justice Party (Partai Keadilan [PK]). The party was reconstituted as the Prosperous Justice Party in April 2003 because in the 1999 election it failed to meet the 2% electoral threshold required to qualify for participation in the 2004 election. Whereas the PKB and the PAN primarily rely on historical mass-based Islamic organisations, the PKS represents relatively new social forces that emerged during the 1980s and 1990s in response to Suharto’s repressive policies towards Islamic activism, especially on university campuses (Mietzner, 1999b). Most of the founders and leaders of the PKS are former campus tarbiyah (Islamic moral education) activists who took part in the establishment of the United Action of Indonesian Muslim Students (KAMMI), under which they participated in the 1998 protests that brought Suharto down (Bruinessen, 2003). Contrary to other Indonesian parties that are plagued with patrimonialism and corruption, the PKS emphasises merit rather than personal loyalties and adopts a clear political program with a consistent anti-corruption approach. Although, like other parties, it seeks to increase its membership base, the PKS considers itself as a cadre party, strictly avoiding leaders and activists who may potentially stain or damage the party’s image (Nurwahid and Zulkieflimansyah, 2003). It is not surprising, therefore, to see that, from the eight major political parties that contested both the 1999 and 2004 elections, the PKS was the only party which managed to considerably increase its share of the vote. As such, by initiating a policy-oriented competition, which may lead other parties to follow suite, and providing a successful alternative to patrimonial politics, the PKS may lead to the institutionalisation of political parties and ‘contribute to a gradual democratization’ and consolidation (Bruinessen, 2003). Surveys of public attitudes, on the other hand, demonstrate other important and positive points of democratic consolidation in Indonesia. According to two mass surveys conducted in 2001 and 2002 by the Centre for the Study of Islam and Society at the State Islamic University of Syarif Hidayatullah (PPIM-UIN), a strong majority of Indonesian Muslims support the idea of upholding the democratic system. Namely, about 70% of all respondents in ‘the two surveys support the idea that democracy, relative to other forms of government, is best for the country’ (Mujani, 2004: 241). Consequently, democracy in Indonesia is by and large consolidated according to the theories that consider a democracy to be consolidated when a Asian Journal of Political Science 167 ‘majority of public opinion holds the belief that democratic procedures and institutions are the most appropriate way to govern collective life’ (Linz and Stepan, 1996: 6). This is a strong indication that the Indonesian public is not likely to lend support to any potential undemocratic alternative, which minimises the threats of democratic breakdown and enhances the prospects of democratic consolidation. Consequently, while democratic breakdown has become highly unlikely in Indonesia, at least in the foreseeable future, it can reasonably be asserted that Indonesia’s democracy will most likely survive and continue to progress into a deeper and higher quality. Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Conclusion This article has demonstrated that democracy in Indonesia has been progressing steadily since the fall of Suharto’s New Order in 1998. The 2004 legislative and direct presidential elections mark the end of the transition to democracy and the start of the phase of democratic consolidation. During the transitional phase, the Indonesian political elites introduced comprehensive constitutional and legislative reforms that democratised the structure of the representative and executive institutions as well as the political process. These reforms included an effective separation of powers, an enhancement of the electoral system and the facilitation of political participation. They also removed Suharto-era restrictions and authoritarian legacies. The emergence of the MPR as a major player helped minimise the possibility of the reemergence of a new presidential dictatorship. Furthermore, the main practical achievements of the democratisation process were realised through the 1999 and 2004 free and fair legislative elections and the peaceful rotations of presidential power, especially with the introduction of direct presidential elections and its successful implementation in 2004. In other words, the Indonesian political landscape today is mainly characterised by frequent, free and fair elections, effective elected officials, separation of powers, inclusive suffrage, freedom of expression, the independence of the media and associational autonomy. Consequently, according to most theories of procedural democracy, Indonesia today enjoys the main attributes of a democratic country and has entered the camp of consolidating democracies. With regard to the extent to which democratic practices have become consolidated and institutionalised, the article has demonstrated that Indonesia has made significant progress, though there still remain some very important challenges and weaknesses to be addressed. Almost all authoritarian legacies and undemocratic alternatives have been eliminated, all significant political actors have demonstrated a consistent commitment to the democratic rules of the game, several democratic and peaceful rotations of power have occurred and a strong majority of public support for upholding the democratic system has developed. On the other hand, the most significant challenges to the deepening of democratic consolidation are mainly related to the role of the military and the process of the institutionalisation of democratic Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 168 L. Abdulbaki practices, especially the development of less patrimonial-oriented and more policydriven electoral competition. Although many positive steps have been taken to promote the return of the military to the barracks and to establish civilian supremacy and control over it, many challenges that hamper the progress of democratic consolidation still persist. On the one hand, the TNI formally relinquished its dual function and withdrew from its political role. The military’s reserved representation in parliament has been totally eliminated, military officers are now prohibited from taking positions in the bureaucracy while in service, and the police force is no longer controlled by the military. On the other, efforts to dismantle the TNI’s territorial structure have not been successful and the military has been able to maintain its business activities that are largely beyond the control of the democratically elected government. The continuous, though slow, pace of civilmilitary reforms, however, will most likely lead to the consignment of the military to the barracks and eventually facilitate the deepening of democratic practices. The development of political programs and less patrimonial or more policy-driven electoral competition is another important aspect hindering the full consolidation of democracy in Indonesia. In order to attract the electoral vote, all Indonesian political parties, especially Islamic parties with the notable exception of the PKS, rely mainly on charismatic leaders or social organisations rather than political programs and policies. Although the PAN and the PKB formally adopted the national ideology of Pancasila as their official ideological basis, instead of developing policies and programs, they have built upon the personal popularity of Rais and Wahid and have relied heavily on the mass-based Islamic organisations of Muhammadiyah and NU, respectively, for their membership and electoral support. The PKS, however, is the only party which primarily emphasises merit rather than personal loyalties. It has also managed to develop a clear political program with a consistent anti-corruption approach, excluding leaders and activists who may tarnish the party’s image from its ranks. Therefore, the PKS, especially considering its success in the 2004 elections, may lead to more policy-oriented electoral competition and contribute to the consolidation of democracy in Indonesia in the foreseeable future. Notes [1] [2] [3] In this context, Dahl uses the term ‘polyarchy’ as an alternative to democracy to protest that ‘no large system in the real world is fully democratized’ (1971: 8). The amendments include the First Amendment of 19 October 1999, the Second Amendment of 18 August 2000, the Third Amendment of 9 November 2001 and the Fourth Amendment of 11 August 2002 (for the full text see, MPR [2002]). Suharto’s family members who were ousted from their seats in the MPR included his eldest daughter, Siti Hardiyanti Rukmana; younger daughter, Titiek Prabowo; sons Hutomo Mandala Putra and Bambang Trihatmodjo; daughter-in-law Halimah Bambang Tri; halfbrother Probosutedjo and cousin Sudwikatmono. According to the then Golkar’s Deputy Chairman, Irsyad Sudiro, the action represented a ‘political commitment to take steps in purging Golkar of corruption, collusion and nepotism’ (Asiaweek, 1998). Asian Journal of Political Science [4] 169 Pancasila refers to the five principles that constitute the national ideology adopted in the constitution. They include: kebangsaan (nationalism), peri-kemanusiaan (humanism), mufakat (deliberative democracy), kesejahteraan sosial (social justice) and ketuhanan (belief in God). Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 References Abootalebi, A. R. (2000). Islam and Democracy: State-Society Relations in Developing Countries 19801994. New York: Garland. Agüero, F. (1997). ‘Toward Civilian Supremacy in South America’, in L. Diamond, M. Plattner, Y. Chu and H. Tien (eds.), Consolidating the Third Wave Democracies: Themes and Perspectives. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 177206. Almond, G. (1980). ‘The Intellectual History of the Civic Culture Concept’, in G. Almond and S. Verba (eds.), The Civic Culture Revisited. Boston: Little, Brown, pp. 136. Almond, G. and Verba, S. (eds.) (1963). The Civic Culture: Political Attitudes and Democracy in Five Nations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Asia Foundation. (2003). ‘Democracy in Indonesia: A Survey of the Indonesian Electorate 2003’, The Asia Foundation Report, November. Available at: http://www.asiafoundation.org/pdf/ democracy_in_indonesia.pdf. Asiaweek. (1998). ‘Suharto’s Family Members Ousted by Indonesia’s Ruling Party’, August 7. Available at: http://www-cgi.cnn.com/ASIANOW/asiaweek/98/0807/feat6.html. Azra, A. (2006). Indonesia, Islam, and Democracy: Dynamics in a Global Context. Jakarta: Solstice. Barron, P., Nathan, M. and Welsh, B. (2005). ‘Consolidating Indonesia’s Democracy: Conflict, Institutions and the ‘‘Local’’ in the 2004 Legislative Elections’. Conflict Prevention & Reconstruction Paper No. 31, Social Development Papers, The World Bank. Available at: http://www-wds.worldbank.org/servlet/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2006/01/31/000090341_ 20060131134151/Rendered/PDF/349900IND0Democracy0WP31.pdf. Bruinessen, M. V. (2003). ‘Post-Suharto Muslim Engagements with Civil Society and Democratisation’, paper presented at the Third International Conference and Workshop ‘Indonesia in Transition’. Universitas Indonesia, Depok, 2428 August. Available at: http://www.let.uu.nl/ martin.vanbruinessen/personal/publications/Post_Suharto_Islam_and_civil_society.htm. Budiman, A. (1998). ‘Friend or Foe?’, Inside Indonesia, 54 (AprilJune). Available at: http:// www.insideindonesia.org/edit54/budiman.htm. Budiman, A. (1999). ‘The 1998 Crisis: Change and Continuity in Indonesia’, in A. Budiman, B. Hatley and D. Kingsbury (eds.), Reformasi: Crisis and Social Change in Indonesia. Clayton, Australia: Monash Asia Institute, pp. 4158. Chipman, J. (ed.) (2006). The Military Balance. London: Routledge. Chu, Y., Diamond, L. and Shin, D. C. (2001). ‘Halting Progress in Korea and Taiwan’, Journal of Democracy, 12 (1): 122136. Dahl, R. (1971). Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Dahl, R. (1998). On Democracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Diamond, L. (1992). ‘Economic Development and Democracy Reconsidered’, American Behavioral Scientist, 35 (45): 450499. Diamond, L. (2003). ‘Can the Whole World Become Democratic? Democracy, Development, and International Policies’, Paper (No 0305), Center for the Study of Democracy, University of California, Irvine. Diederich, M. (2002). ‘A Closer Look at ‘‘Dakwah’’ and Politics in Indonesia: The Partai Keadilan’, Archipel, 64: 101115. Eickelman, D. F. (1997). ‘Muslim Politics: The Prospects for Democracy in North Africa and the Middle East’, in J. P. Entelis (ed.), Islam, Democracy, and the State in North Africa. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, pp. 1742. Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 170 L. Abdulbaki Esposito, J. (1995). The Islamic Threat: Myth or Reality? Oxford: Oxford University Press. Esposito, J. and Voll, J. (1996). Islam and Democracy. New York: Oxford University Press. Falaakh, M. F. (2001). ‘Nahdlatul Ulama and Civil Society in Indonesia’, in M. Nakamura, S. Siddique and O. Bajunid (eds.), Islam and Civil Society in Southeast Asia. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, pp. 3342. Fealy, G. and Platzdasch, B. (2005). ‘The Masyumi Legacy: Between Islamist Idealism and Political Exigency’, Studia Islamika, 12 (1): 7399. Freedman, A. (2007). ‘Consolidation or Withering Away of Democracy? Political Changes in Thailand and Indonesia’, Asian Affairs: An American Review, 33 (4): 195216. Fukuyama, F. (1992). The End of History and the Last Man. New York: Free Press. Gallie, W. B. (1956). ‘Essentially Contested Concepts’, Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, 56: 167 198. Greenlees, D. (2005). ‘Indonesia Wants its Army Out of Business’, International Herald Tribune, 4 May. Available at: http://www.iht.com/articles/2005/05/03/business/rupiah.php. Hefner, R. (2000). Civil Islam: Muslims and Democratization in Indonesia. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Human Rights Watch. (2006). ‘Too High a Price: The Human Rights Cost of the Indonesian Military’s Economic Activities’, Human Rights Watch, 18 (5[C]). Available at: http:// www.hrw.org/reports/2006/indonesia0606/indonesia0606webwcover.pdf. Huntington, S. (1984). ‘Will More Countries Become Democratic?’, Political Science Quarterly, 99 (2): 193218. Huntington, S. (1991). The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press. Huntington, S. and Nelson, J. M. (1976). No Easy Choice: Political Participation in Developing Countries. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Jakarta Post. (1999a). ‘Elections Body Membership Valid Until 2003: Syarwan’, 25 June. Available at: http://www.thejakartapost.com/Archives/ArchivesDet2.asp?FileID=19990625.@04. Jakarta Post. (1999b). ‘Gen. Wiranto Says Military Internal Reform Going on’, 10 May. Available at: http://www.thejakartapost.com/headlines.asp. Jakarta Post. (2000). ‘PKB to Have Non-Muslim Officials: Matori’, 6 March. Available at: http:// www.thejakartapost.com/Archives/ArchivesDet2.asp?FileID=20000306.A06. Jamhari. (1999). ‘Islamic Political Parties: Threats or Prospects’, in G. Forrester (ed.), Post-Soeharto Indonesia: Renewal or Chaos? Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies. Juoro, U. (2006). ‘Democratic Consolidation in Indonesia under SBY’, Opinion Asia, 11 December. Available at: http://www.opinionasia.org/DemocraticConsolidationinIndonesia. King, D. (2003). Half-Hearted Reform: Electoral Institutions and the Struggle for Democracy in Indonesia. Westport, CT: Praeger. Koekebakker, W. (1994). ‘Cracks in the Cilangkap Bastion: The Armed Forces in Suharto’s Indonesia’, in European Network Against the Arms Trade (ed.), STOP Arming Indonesia. Amsterdam: ENAAT. Available at: http://www.stopwapenhandel.org/publicaties/boekenbro chures/Stop%20arming%20indonesia.pdf. Lewis, B. (1994). The Shaping of the Modern Middle East. New York: Oxford University Press. Linz, J. J. and Stepan, A. (1996). Problems of Democratic Transition and Consolidation: Southern Europe, South America, and Post-Communist Europe. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Linz, J. J. and Stepan, A. (1997). ‘Toward Consolidated Democracies’, in L. Diamond, M. Plattner, Y. Chu and H. Tien (eds.), Consolidating the Third Wave Democracies: Themes and Perspectives. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 1433. Linz, J. J. and Stepan A. (2001). ‘Defining and Crafting Democratic Transition, Constitutions, and Consolidation’, in R. W. Liddle (ed.), Crafting Indonesian Democracy. Bandung: Mizan, pp. 1734. Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Asian Journal of Political Science 171 Lipset, S. M. (1960). Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics. London: Heinemann. Lipset, S. M. (1994). ‘The Social Requisites of Democracy Revisited’, American Sociological Review, 59 (1): 122. Majelis Permusyawaratan Rakyat [People’s Consultative Assembly, Republic of Indonesia] (MPR). (1999). Tahun 1999. Jakarta: General Secretary of the MPR, Republic of Indonesia. Available at: http://www.mpr.go.id/index.php?lang=id§ion ketetapan. Masters, E. (1999). ‘Indonesia’s 1999 Elections: A Second Chance for Democracy’, Asia Society, May. Available at: http://www.asiasociety.org/publications/indonesia/#The%201999%20Election %20Laws. Mietzner, M. (1999a). ‘From Suharto to Habibie: the Indonesian Armed Forces and Political Islam During the Transition’, in G. Forrester (ed.), Post-Suharto Indonesia: Renewal or Chaos? Bathhurst: Crawford House Publishing, pp. 65102. Mietzner, M. (1999b). ‘Nationalism and Islamic Politics: Political Islam in the Post-Suharto Era’, in A. Budiman, B. Hatley and D. Kingsbury (eds.), Reformasi: Crisis and Change in Indonesia. Clayton: Monash Asia Institute. Mernissi, F. (1992). Islam and Democracy: Fear of the Modern World. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. MPR. (2002). ‘The 1945 Constitution of the Republic of Indonesia’. Amended 1999, 2000, 2001 and 2002. Available at: http://www.mpr.go.id/index.php?lang=en§ion=uud1945_iframe&id=1 &judul=THE%201945%20CONSTITUTION. Mujani, S. (2004). ‘Religious Democrats: Democratic Culture and Muslim Political Participation in Post-Suharto Indonesia’, unpublished dissertation, Ohio State University, Columbus. Nurhasim, M. (2005). ‘Why the Military do Business? An Introductory Note’, in M. Nurhasim (ed.) Practices of Military Business: Experiences from Indonesia, Burma, Philippines and South Korea. Jakarta: RIDEP Institute. Nurwahid, H. and Zulkieflimansyah. (2003). ‘The Justice Party and Democracy: A Journey of a Thousand Miles Starts with a Single Step’, in R. W. Liddle, M. I. Alief, H. Nurwahid and Zulkieflimansyah, Piety and Pragmatism: Trends in Islamic Politics, Asia Program Special Report (No 110), Woodrow Wilson International Centre for Scholars. Available at: http:// www.wilsoncenter.org/topics/pubs/asiarpt_110.pdf. O’Donnell, G. (1992). ‘Transitions, Continuities, and Paradoxes’, in S. Mainwaring, G. O’Donnell and J. S. Valenzuela (eds), Issues in Democratic Consolidation: The New South American Democracies in Comparative Perspective. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press, pp. 1756. Osaghae, E. (1995). ‘The Study of Political Transitions in Africa’, Review of African Political Economy, 22 (64): 183197. Paras Indonesia. (2007). ‘U.S. House of Representatives Calls for Human Rights Accountability and Military Reform in Indonesia’, 26 June. Available at: http://www.parasindonesia.com/ news_read.php?gid=301. Przeworski, A. (1991). Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Rabasa, A. and Haseman, J. (2002). The Military and Democracy in Indonesia: Challenges, Politics, and Power. Santa Monica: RAND. Rose, R. (1997). ‘Where Are Postcommunist Countries Going?’, Journal of Democracy, 8 (3): 92108. Schedler, A. (2002). ‘Elections Without Democracy: The Menu of Manipulation’, Journal of Democracy, 13 (2): 3946. Schmitter, P. and Karl, T. L. (1991). ‘What Democracy Is . . . and Is Not’, Journal of Democracy, 2 (3): 7588. Schneider, C. and Schmitter P. (2004). ‘Liberalization, Transition and Consolidation: Measuring the Components of Democratization’, Democratization, 11 (5): 6168. Schumpeter, J. (1947). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper. Schwarz, A. (1999). A Nation in Waiting: Indonesia’s Search for Stability. Sydney: Allen and Unwin. 172 L. Abdulbaki Downloaded by [Koc University] at 06:48 31 July 2013 Schwarz, P. (1999). ‘Indonesia awaits its future after election’, Jakarta Post, 27 May. Available at: http://www.thejakartapost.com/Archives/ArchivesDet2.asp?FileID=19990527.C03. Tornquist, O. (2002). ‘What’s Wrong with Indonesia’s Democratisation?’, Southeast Asian Journal of Social Sciences, 30 (3): 547569. Tornquist, O. (2004). ‘Labour and Democracy? Reflections on the Indonesian Impasse’, Journal of Contemporary Asia, 34 (3): 377399. Uhlin, A. (2000). ‘Towards an Integration of Domestic and Transnational Dimensions of Democratisation: Regime Transition in Indonesia’, paper presented at the Joint Sessions of the European Consortium for Political Research (ECPR), Copenhagen, 1419 April. Webber, D. (2005). ‘A Consolidated Patrimonial Democracy? Democratization in Post-Suharto Indonesia’, paper presented at the Joint Sessions of the ECPR, Granada, 1419 April.