the full issue
Transcription
the full issue
4th Quarter 2014 | Volume 2, Issue 4 The Quarterly Journal of The Clearing House Financial Resiliency Promoting Stability and Growth Macroprudential Policy and Financial Resiliency andall S. Kroszner, Booth School of R Business, University of Chicago Macroeconomic Modeling and Financial Stability ndrew W. Lo, Sloan School of A Management, MIT The Implications of Higher Capital Requirements Alexey Levkov and Clark Peterson, The Clearing House Balancing the Risks and Benefits of Uncleared Swaps Donna Parisi and Barnabas Reynolds, Shearman & Sterling LLP My Perspective Robert Ceske of KPMG on Liquidity Also Featuring State of Banking With Brian Moynihan, Chairman and CEO of Bank of America Prospects for Financial Services Legislation in the 114th Congress Samuel Woodall III, Sullivan & Cromwell LLP TCH Analytics A Quantitative Snapshot of Trends in Banking When your business succeeds, we all succeed. At M&T Bank, we understand the importance of building long-term relationships with our customers and communities. It’s what we’ve been doing for more than 155 years. It’s why we support our neighborhoods and why we keep banking decisions local. See the difference our personal, local and long-term commitment can make. Stop by an M&T branch, call us at 1-800-724-6070 or visit us at mtb.com/business. mtb.com ©2014 M&T Bank. Member FDIC. Coming Up for Banking Perspective In its next issue, Banking Perspective will feature commentary and analysis on recent trends in the global economy and the unique challenges to foreign banking organizations posed by the international regulatory framework. The first quarter issue of Banking Perspective will also feature reflection by CFPB Director Richard Cordray on efforts to enhance consumer protection. How to Submit How to Subscribe Banking Perspective welcomes your submissions. Articles should be between 2,500-4,000 words and should support an identifiable position in the context of bank policy or bank payments issues. While technical in nature, articles should be clear, concise, readable, and accessible to individuals with varying degrees of knowledge of the banking industry. Authors should avoid undue focus on any individual financial firm. The Clearing House will copyedit all accepted submissions with the full cooperation of the author. The author will have final approval of all content. Once published, The Clearing House retains the right to publish and distribute material at its discretion. Banking Perspective, the quarterly journal of The Clearing House, is a forum for thought leadership from banking industry executives, regulators, academics, policy experts, industry observers, and others. Articles focus on themes in the bank regulatory landscape and innovation trends in bank payments, providing timely analysis of the most important issues shaping today’s banking industry. To submit an article for consideration, e-mail [email protected]. To subscribe, visit: theclearinghouse.org/publications/subscribe-bankingperspective. 4th Quarter 2014 | Volume 2, Issue 4 The Quarterly Journal of The Clearing House Featured Articles 16 Fire Extinguishers and Smoke Detectors: Macroprudential Policy and Financial Resiliency Since the financial crisis, a debate has emerged about the appropriate role of central banks as an ex ante “smoke detector” and as an ex post “fire extinguisher.” While a greater focus on financial stability concerns is valuable, policymakers should not underestimate the difficulty of undertaking effective macroprudential policy and should be mindful of significant challenges to implementing such policy, challenges that could ultimately undermine market discipline. by R andall S. Kroszner, Booth School of Business, University of Chicago 22 Macroeconomic Modeling and Financial Stability: Lessons from the Crisis The dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model (DSGE) marked a major milestone by capturing the dynamic change of economic variables over time. However, many DSGE models were exposed as having omitted critical structural linkages relevant to the financial crisis. To address these deficiencies, existing DSGE models should be enhanced to better incorporate the role of the financial sector and financial markets. In addition, these models should reexamine key micro-foundations of the model and consider behavioral components. by Andrew W. Lo, Sloan School of Management, MIT 32 State of Banking: A Conversation With Brian Moynihan Paul Saltzman interviews Bank of America Chairman and CEO Brian Moynihan, who discusses the opportunities facing the banking industry, his new role as Chairman of The Clearing House, and the implications of technology growth on cybersecurity, payments, and bank business models. 36 Too Much of a Good Thing: The Implications of Higher Capital Requirements Capital requirements are important to ensure that externalities associated with a bank’s failure are borne by the bank alone. However, there are both private and social costs associated with requiring banks to hold more capital. Empirical and theoretical evidence indicate that there are significant trade-offs in requiring higher levels of bank equity capital. Policymakers should seek to identify the costs and benefits of requiring more capital at banks and calibrate rulemakings accordingly. by Alexey Levkov and Clark Peterson, The Clearing House 50 The Art of the Possible: Prospects for Financial Services Legislation in the 114th Congress With a Republican-controlled Congress and a Democratic president, the conventional wisdom is that the next two years will portend an extended and partisan political stalemate that will stymie any prospect for enactment of meaningful financial services legislation. However, real opportunities for the advancement of financial services legislation are in play. In fact, if recent history is any indicator, Congressional Republicans will have the chance to do something that has been off limits for the last several years: amend Dodd-Frank. by Samuel Woodall III, Sullivan & Cromwell LLP 62 Margin for Error: Balancing the Risks and Benefits of Uncleared Swaps Margin requirements for uncleared derivatives are intended to reduce counterparty credit risk, limit contagion, and incentivize the central clearing of derivatives trades. However, they risk fueling potentially negative outcomes such as straining market liquidity and subsequently driving activity to the shadows. In addition, the ambiguous scope of their extraterritorial application threatens to introduce new forms of uncertainty and legal risk into cross-border transactions. by Donna Parisi and Barnabas Reynolds, Shearman & Sterling LLP D e pa r t m e n t s 8 For the Record 10 My Perspective TCH Association President Paul Saltzman calls for a reconceptualization of banking resilience and discusses key considerations for macroprudential policy with this in mind. As banks and other market participants were under-prepared for the liquidity challenges of the crisis, heightened focus on liquidity is justified. However, regulators should be wary of how new liquidity regulations interact with capital rules, impact greater risk management practices, and drive liquidity risk to the shadows. by Robert Ceske, KPMG 48 72 74 84 86 TCH Analytics A snapshot of selected trends in the banking sector. Editor Clark Peterson Associate Editor David Helene Banking Perspective is the quarterly journal of The Clearing House. Its aim is to inform financial industry leaders and the policymaking community on developments in bank policy and payments. The journal is a forum for thought-leadership from banking industry executives, regulators, academics, policy experts, industry observers, and others. Established in 1853, The Clearing House is the oldest banking association and payments company in the United States. It is owned by the world’s largest commercial banks, which collectively hold more than half of all U.S. deposits and which employ over one million people in the United States and more than two million people worldwide. The Clearing House Association L.L.C. is a nonpartisan advocacy organization that represents the interests of its owner banks by developing and promoting policies to support a safe, sound and competitive banking system that serves customers and communities. Its affiliate, The Clearing House Payments Company L.L.C., which is regulated as a systemically important financial market utility, owns and operates payments technology infrastructure that provides safe and efficient payment, clearing and settlement services to financial institutions, and leads innovation and thought leadership activities for the next generation of payments. It clears almost $2 trillion each day, representing nearly half of all automated clearing house, funds transfer and check-image payments made in the U.S. By the Numbers A quantitative look at the contributions of banks to the U.S. economy. Research Rundown Highlights from academic and policy research on issues in the banking and payments industry. Featured Moments Copyright 2014 The Clearing House Association L.L.C. All rights reserved. All content is owned by The Clearing House Association L.L.C. or its licensors. The views expressed herein are not necessarily those of The Clearing House Association L.L.C., its affiliates, customers or owners. Any use or reproduction of any of the contents hereof without the express written permission of The Clearing House Association L.L.C. is strictly prohibited. Visual highlights from TCH’s Annual Fall Leadership Dinner. In the Vault An early image from TCH’s 161-year past. The Clearing House 450 West 33rd Street New York, NY 10001 212.613.0100 1001 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW Washington, DC 20004 202.649.4600 Contributors Randall Kroszner Randall S. Kroszner served as a Governor of the Federal Reserve System from March 2006 until January 2009. During his time as a member of the Federal Reserve Board, he chaired the committee on Supervision and Regulation of Banking Institutions and the committee on Consumer and Community Affairs. He also represented the Federal Reserve Board on the Financial Stability Forum (now called the Financial Stability Board), the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, and the Central Bank Governors of the American Continent. He is currently a Research Associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research and serves on the Committees on Economic Statistics and on Economic Education of the American Economics Association. Dr. Kroszner was a member of the President’s Council of Economic Advisers (CEA) from 2001 to 2003. Alexey Levkov Dr. Levkov is responsible for quantitative analysis supporting the advocacy initiatives at The Clearing House, primarily focusing on capital and liquidity. Prior to joining The Clearing House, Dr. Levkov was a senior financial economist in the Supervision and Regulation Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. 6 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Between 2011 and 2014 he served as a lead model developer for the supervisory wholesale model for CCAR, working with teams at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and the Board of Governors. His other responsibilities included reviewing advanced-approach risk models and working with the Basel Coordination Committee (BCC) as well as conducting research related to financial stability and labor markets. Dr. Levkov’s work has been published in several academic journals and he is a recipient of the Brattle Group Award for a distinguished paper published in The Journal of Finance in 2010. He received his Ph.D. and M.A. in Economics from Brown University and his B.A. in Economics and Statistics from The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Israel. Andrew W. Lo Andrew W. Lo is the Charles E. and Susan T. Harris Professor, a Professor of Finance, and the Director of the Laboratory for Financial Engineering at the MIT Sloan School of Management. Prior to MIT Sloan, he taught at the University of Pennsylvania Wharton School as the W.P. Carey Assistant Professor of Finance from 1984 to 1987, and as the W.P. Carey Associate Professor of Finance from 1987 to 1988. His research interests include the empirical validation and implementation of financial asset pricing models; the pricing of options and other derivative securities; financial engineering and risk management; and, most recently, evolutionary and neurobiological models of individual risk preferences and financial markets, among many others. Dr. Lo is founder and chief scientific officer of AlphaSimplex Group, LLC, a quantitative investment management company based in Cambridge, Massachusetts. Donna M. Parisi Donna M. Parisi is a partner, Co-Practice Group Leader of Shearman & Sterling’s Asset Management Group (which includes the firm’s Derivatives & Structured Products team) and former member of the firm’s Executive Group. Ms. Parisi’s practice focuses on derivative, structured product, securitization, capital market and commodities matters. Legal directories such as Chambers Global, Chambers USA, Legal 500 US and IFLR 1000have for several years consistently ranked Ms. Parisi as a leader in her field, and in 2014 Ms. Parisi was selected for a Lawyer Monthly Women in Law award in recognition of outstanding legal work. Specifically, Ms. Parisi has assisted clients in the development and structuring of new financial products and is experienced in the negotiation and documentation of OTC derivative transactions, including equity, credit, hedge fund, fixed income, commodity and currency swaps and options, among others. Clark W. Peterson Clark Peterson is Senior Vice President of Strategy and Public Policy at The Clearing House. He focuses on policy research and analysis and helps lead the strategic and operational agenda of The Clearing House Association. He is also the editor of The Clearing House’s quarterly publication, Banking Perspective, which he helped found. Mr. Peterson began his career on Capitol Hill. He was a policy adviser in the U.S. Senate, focusing on economic, fiscal, and financial policy issues. He served as Legislative Director for a senior member of the Senate and was a Legislative Assistant before that. During this time, he advised on the enactment of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (2010). He also advised a member of the House Agriculture Committee during consideration of the Food, Conservation and Energy Act of 2008. Mr. Peterson received Bachelors of Arts degrees in both economics and political science from Hillsdale College. He holds a MBA from the Harvard Business School. Barnabas Reynolds Barnabas Reynolds is head of the global Financial Institutions Advisory & Financial Regulatory Group at Sherman & Sterling. He advises the full range of market participants on their businesses in the London and European markets. His practice focuses on global legal risk management, including in the context of cross-border legal, regulatory and insolvency regimes. In addition, from Q1 2010 to Q1 2014, he served as an elected member of the firm’s Policy Committee. Barnabas is recognized as a leading UK and EU financial regulatory lawyer. He was named the Times Lawyer of the Week in December 2013, is on the 2013 London Super Lawyers list and was selected as one of the Best Lawyers in the UK in insurance law. Cromwell from Capitol Hill, where he served on the staff of the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs of the U.S. House of Representatives. Mr. Reynolds has been actively involved in helping to shape, analyze and comment upon the global regulatory reforms that arose out of the recent financial crisis. Samuel Woodall III Sam Woodall is a partner in Sullivan & Cromwell’s General Practice Group. He represents a variety of clients before the U.S. Congress, as well as executive branch and federal financial regulatory agencies. Mr. Woodall has participated, on behalf of the Firm’s clients, in the Congressional deliberations leading to enactment of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (1999), the USA PATRIOT Act (2001), the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (2002), the Financial Services Regulatory Relief Act (2006) and, most recently, the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (2010), as well as the regulatory implementation of these statutes. He has also advised the Firm’s clients in connection with federal legislation and regulation governing student lending, industrial banks, private equity firms, and Government Sponsored Enterprises. Mr. Woodall came to Sullivan & Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 7 For the Record Paul S altzman President of The Clearing House Association, EVP and General Counsel of The Clearing House Payments Company The banking system plays a unique and vital role in the economy’s health. The services and functions that banks perform comprise our economy’s circulatory system, creating and delivering the financial equivalent of oxygen throughout the economy to allow it to grow. As such, banks enable consumers, businesses, and industries to achieve a level of consumption and output that would otherwise be impossible—contributing to job creation, higher living standards, and long-term growth and prosperity. stable funding ratio and a total loss absorbing capacity requirement—reached finalization at the international level. Meant to ensure sufficient long-term liquidity at banks and improve their resolvability, respectively, these two reforms have been viewed as key missing pieces in safeguarding the stability of the system. The financial crisis demonstrated, however, that the consequences of a disruption to the system can put our economy on the brink of cardiac arrest. Just as it’s critical for all of us to ensure our own health—to exercise, eat well, and go to the doctor—banks and policymakers must ensure the resilience of the banking system. I believe that the concept of banking system resilience must incorporate a key trade-off that’s been largely overlooked: the trade-off between stability and growth. Banking system resilience, properly understood, should not refer merely to the ex post state of the industry in the wake of a shock. Rather, the appropriate concept of resilience must also capture the ex ante ability of the system to effectively perform the critical services and functions that support economic growth. We must begin to assess not only the components of financial stability but also those related to macroeconomic performance: credit extension, cost of credit, and market liquidity, for example. In the traditional view, this means that we must ensure that the system, on a standalone basis, can withstand shocks and continue to perform its functions in the face of such shocks. This has been the ultimate goal of our post-crisis regulatory reform efforts. Understandably, policymakers have primarily sought to achieve stability through the development and subsequent implementation of a whole host of new regulatory reforms. In general, these reforms aim to ensure appropriate levels of capital and liquidity at banks, reduce overall levels of interconnectedness, and ensure the resolvability of any failing bank without the need of taxpayer funds. Substantial progress has been made. One need look no further than the last few weeks, during which two critical measures—the net 8 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 In the wake of all of these new regulatory reforms, the banking system is certainly more stable. But it is unclear to me that it is sufficiently resilient. What do I mean by this? Our bank regulatory framework must be crafted with this equilibrium in mind. We should seek an optimal state where regulations provide for a banking system not only stable enough to withstand systemic shocks but also robust enough to maximize sustainable economic growth. The macroprudential approach to financial regulatory reform has been the approach predominantly adopted by regulators since the crisis. This approach, however, incorporates substantial regulatory judgment, a time-varying component, and can easily veer into the top-down economic fine-tuning long discarded in American economic policymaking. There are critical trade-offs to this approach that cannot be ignored. As I have said before, unlike microprudential mistakes, macroprudential mistakes are likely to have macroeconomic consequences. It is therefore of critical importance that we understand the trade-offs involved and that rules are calibrated accordingly. Former Federal Reserve Governor Randy Kroszner covers this ground well in his article Fire Extinguishers and Smoke Detectors: Macroprudential Policy and Financial Resiliency. He outlines the objectives policymakers should strive for in constructing macroprudential rules, and he argues that “it is crucial…to assess the costs and benefits in terms of the potential benefits of greater stability and resiliency against potential costs in terms of lower economic growth.” This is an enormously challenging proposition, and he therefore cautions policymakers on the certain pitfalls they may face, including difficulties related to developing appropriate “warning flags,” the appearance of arbitrary decision making, and political risk. The debate over the appropriate level of bank capital requirements illustrates the growth-stability concept of financial resiliency. In their article Too Much of a Good Thing: The Implications of Heightened Capital Requirements, Alexey Levkov and Clark Peterson use standard corporate finance frameworks to describe the firm-level trade-offs associated with a bank’s capital structure. They conclude that bank capital structure decisions matter, and that there are costs and benefits associated with higher equity levels. They connect the firm-level trade-offs to the macroeconomic trade-offs with respect to stability and growth, and then recommend that policymakers weigh these trade-offs carefully when contemplating heightened capital requirements. In addition to assessing the trade-offs inherent in particular regulations, like capital, it’s crucial that we begin to assess how different types of regulations are interacting with each other in a comprehensive way. The capital framework, for example, is comprised of a risk-based approach, a leverage ratio, and annual stress testing. Similarly, the liquidity framework is comprised of a short-term liquidity rule, a long-term liquidity rule, annual stress testing, and likely a forthcoming rule governing short-term wholesale funding. Then there are single counterparty credit limits, rules to enhance resolvability, derivatives requirements, and structural requirements, just to name a few. We need to carefully examine how these pieces interact. Robert Ceske of KPMG highlights a prime example of this need in this issue’s My Perspective, in which he articulates how our approach to capital and liquidity risk management is currently bifurcated and how the critical connections between capital and liquidity are disconcertingly underemphasized by the regulatory framework. Rob suggests that the industry and regulators work together to better capture the interconnectivity of capital and liquidity and ensure that liquidity issues and challenges are integrated and assessed in the capital planning process. Like Rob, I believe it is critical to take a hard look at the complete set of trade-offs and net impact of these rulemakings, so that we understand how they affect overall resilience. In addition to the net trade-offs of these rulemakings, it is also important to understand the net impact of these reforms on overall risk. Donna Parisi and Barney Reynolds describe how margin requirements for uncleared swaps, for example, could, on a net basis increase overall risk in their article Margin for Error: Balancing the Risks and Benefits of Uncleared Swaps. By straining market liquidity, complicating cross-border transactions, and transferring risks to shadow banks, this measure has clear implications for resilience. If a core effect of rules is to push risk to a part of the financial system that is held to a lower standard of risk management and stability, they could in fact adversely affect overall resilience. As we continue to complete and refine the post-crisis regulatory framework, we must also begin to look forward. People often wonder how we missed the warning signs from the last crisis and how we can ensure that we don’t miss the warning signs of the next one. One technical, but fascinating, component of this is the world of macroeconomic modeling. MIT’s Andrew Lo, in his article Macroeconomic Modeling and Financial Stability: Lessons from the Crisis, discusses the previous shortcomings of our macroeconomic models—namely, that the pre-crisis vintage didn’t incorporate a financial system into the models themselves. Andy argues that dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, which are the state-of-theart pre- and post-crisis macroeconomic models, need to be better aligned to the financial sector and better reflect its true impact on the greater economy. To steal a quote from Andy’s piece, “being precisely wrong is not as helpful as being approximately right.” We cannot afford for our financial regulatory framework to be precisely wrong. A better conceptualization of banking resilience that recognizes important trade-offs can help us get the balance approximately right. Lastly, we are thrilled to feature a conversation with Brian Moynihan, Chairman and CEO of Bank of America and the incoming Chairman of The Clearing House, in this issue’s State of Banking interview. He offers insights on critical issues the banking industry faces—insights that only an industry leader like Brian can provide. He covers U.S. and global economic growth, the need for a customer-driven strategy, and how the industry can adapt to rapid technological change. We at The Clearing House look forward to tackling many of these issues under Brian’s leadership in 2015. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 9 My Perspective Liquidity risk received little attention prior to the recent financial crisis. Since then, however, banks have improved their understanding of the challenges they face in this area. The crisis also led to heightened regulatory requirements for bank liquidity risk management. On September 3, 2014, U.S. regulators released the final rule for the Liquidity Coverage Ratio (“LCR”). On October 31, 2014, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision updated its standard for the Net Stable Funding Ratio (“NSFR”). Robe rt Ceske Principal, KPMG Rob Ceske is a Principal with KPMG LLP and leads the firm’s national treasury and liquidity practices. As a risk practitioner and strategic advisor, Rob has helped financial and nonfinancial companies to improve their funding and liquidity risk management, governance and strategy, as well as their asset/liability management, market, credit and operational risk. Rob served as the Chief Risk Manager for GE/GE Capital’s Corporate Treasury from 2002 to 2010, where he received the 2009 Pinnacle Award and 2006 President’s Award from the Association for Financial Professionals, the GE Treasurer’s Award and two Alexander Hamilton Awards. Rob also worked in derivative product groups at J.P. Morgan and Merrill Lynch. Acknowledgemen t s The author would like to thank Marshal Auron and Jeff Dykstra for their valuable contributions to this article. The views and opinions expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views and opinions of KPMG LLP. Together, these regulatory requirements, once they are fully adopted in the U.S., will increase holdings of liquid assets at regulated financial institutions. But will they really achieve the broader objective of helping create a more stable financial system? Clearly, some banks and other market participants were under-prepared for the liquidity challenges of the crisis and a heightened focus on liquidity is justified. However, liquidity risk is created by maturity transformation, which is a fundamental risk of banking. Holding additional liquidity is always easy to justify. The question is: where’s the limit? While the LCR and NSFR are not at risk of putting banks out of business, are we squeezing on a balloon? Could we be forcing banks to have “too much” liquidity—not too much in the sense that banks are not better protected from liquidity crises than they were in the past, but in the fact that maturity transformation and other fundamental tenets of the banking 10 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 sector could move away from the regulated financial sector? Some of the post-crisis reforms could be shifting us towards a regime where liquidity risk is pushed to those without the traditional liquidity backstop. We have seen this in limited cases so far (e.g., selling mortgage servicing rights to nonbanks, adding call provisions on debt, and adding notice periods on certain withdrawals), but expect more as banks comply with LCR requirements. We should expect that banks, which are now faced with an explicit cost of providing liquidity to customers, will push such liquidity risks to their customers and counterparties, where possible. This is a rational microeconomic decision. However, in the end, will we have created a financial system that is less able to withstand liquidity shocks, as liquidity will increasingly be provided by individuals and companies that do not have access to Federal Reserve, Federal Home Loan Bank system, and other forms of government-supported backstop liquidity? Liquidity crises are driven by a loss of confidence on the part of counterparties, customers, and others who have connections to a financial institution. Government intervention during the crisis supported the liquidity needs of individual firms and the system, but it also served an extremely valuable role of helping restore public confidence in banks and other financial intermediaries. Unfortunately, public (and policymakers’) concerns about Congratulations to H. Rodgin Cohen, Senior Chairman of Sullivan & Cromwell, on receiving our 2014 Chairman’s Lifetime Achievement Award. The award recognizes a leader in the banking field whose professional contributions have positively shaped the industry throughout his or her professional career. Past recipients include former Mayor Michael Bloomberg and former Federal Reserve Vice Chairman Donald Kohn. “too big to fail” have left a persistent desire to avoid a repeat of the government’s support measures. But without similar government support in future crises—even with banks that have more capital and liquidity, might the outcome be worse? The government must be in a position to provide such market confidence in the future. ‘‘ be cautious of unintended consequences. Liquidity regulation also needs greater customization. The LCR does not have any adjustment for banks’ internal strength in risk management, crisis planning, or other such factors in Pillar I liquidity requirements (which currently include holding enough “High Quality Liquid Assets” to cover We should seek broader approaches to liquidity management that take into account other factors, such as capital, risk management, and business mix—and also be cautious of unintended consequences. While there is no “right answer” to how much liquidity to hold (or force banks to hold), a recent Fed comparison of banks’ most severe internal 30-day liquidity stress tests and their LCR calculations showed that the LCR requirement exceeded banks’ most severe internal stress test for two thirds of these banks.1 We should seek broader approaches to liquidity management that take into account other factors, such as capital, risk management, and business mix—and also 1 Miller, Bart, Market & Liquidity Supervision, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, “Liquidity Supervision of Large Banking Organizations,” October 28, 2014 12 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 net outflows in a regulator-prescribed stress environment). As part of Enhanced Prudential Standards requirements, regulators expect firms to create and manage to idiosyncratic liquidity stress measures, but the LCR is the constraint for most. Internal stress tests are meant to complement and supplement the LCR buffer, but when LCR factors are immovable, regardless of individual firm history/behavior, and the LCR ratios are lower than internal stress tests, the LCR becomes the de facto constraint on liquidity. A key concern is that banks’ internal risk management departments will become more focused on managing regulatory constraints and requirements than on managing the risks of the bank (regardless of regulation). Such a response is unavoidable when complying with new regulatory requirements is overwhelming internal risk departments. Bank boards of directors have also felt this strain. During KPMG’s recent governance survey2, numerous directors cited the strain compliance efforts had on their boards and how such requirements necessarily reduced the strategic input that these directors felt they could provide. The challenge is that such a dramatic short-term increase in compliance efforts will by necessity reduce the focus of second- and third-line-of-defense personnel on looking for risks outside of regulatory mandates. We will be well prepared to fight the last crisis, but banks’ internal risk groups, and the diversity of their detection and mitigation techniques, will be weaker relative to an unanticipated crisis. A wise goal would be to balance regulation with the historical “collaborative challenge” between firms and supervisors. There is still much to do in the area of liquidity risk management. While supervisors have moved toward macroprudential supervision for capital and liquidity risk, they are still early in incorporating interconnectedness between firms into supervision. And, to some extent, supervisory and financial institution focus is currently bifurcated between capital and liquidity risk management. However, it is important for both regulators and financial institutions to consider the relationships between these two crucial aspects of financial resiliency. True, elements of 2 KPMG and Association for Financial Professionals, “Raising the Bar for Treasury Risk Governance,” 2014 Our financial regulatory clients rely on the exceptional, collaborative service we deliver. Their success is our focus. Davis Polk’s market-leading Financial Institutions Group represents many of the most important U.S. and non-U.S. banks, broker-dealers, insurance companies, trading markets and investment managers. Our lawyers are at the forefront of advising financial institutions on how new Dodd-Frank Act and bank capital requirements will impact their businesses. For more about our financial regulatory services, please visit davispolk.com or contact: Randall D. Guynn Partner and Head of the Financial Institutions Group [email protected] ■ 212 450 4239 New York Menlo Park Washington DC São Paulo London Paris davispolk.com Madrid Tokyo Beijing Hong Kong © 2014 Davis Polk & Wardwell LLP liquidity risk are captured in CCAR and capital planning, but Pillar I requirements should have a stronger connection between capital and liquidity, as banks with strong capital positions have been much less susceptible to liquidity crises (likely due to their stronger inherent financial resiliency as well as the higher perception of financial strength). There are also opportunities to derive and define alternative liquidity risk measures. We should consider new approaches to help us avert future shocks in addition to capital-liquidity connections. For example, probabilistic approaches, assumptions that take into ‘‘ Looking forward, the industry and regulators should work together to improve liquidity risk management in several areas: and capital risk measures that a firm needs to manage. These measures should be considered in an integrated way. Risk Identification: Liquidity issues and challenges should be specifically identified and inventoried as part of the capital planning exercise to make certain that all risks are integrated and assessed in the capital plan. Regulators and financial institutions need to keep liquidity risk management moving forward in a way that balances safety and soundness with economic growth. We need to ensure that risk managers have adequate time to actually manage risk. Governance: Specific interrelationships in oversight, policies, and measurement should be considered, including connections in committees, memberships, communication of actions, consistency in policies and consideration of risk measures. Supervisory and financial institution focus is currently bifurcated between capital and liquidity risk management. However, it is important for both regulators and financial institutions to consider the interconnections between these two crucial aspects of financial resiliency. account multiple and idiosyncratic risk considerations, and approaches that consider different liquidity buffer levels based on risk levels all may have potential. This is both a regulatory and individual firm challenge: to develop better risk identification and early warning systems to monitor idiosyncratic and systemic risks and proactively address them. 14 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Contingency planning: Capital and liquidity should be considered in a related way (e.g., governance, early warning signals, etc.). Both are important elements in recovery planning. Risk measurement and management: As we transition closer to Basel III implementation, there are multiple liquidity WilmerHale is proud to support The Clearing House. Clients look to our Financial Institutions Practice for assistance with complex, challenging federal regulatory and legislative, litigation, enforcement, and business transaction matters. Our lawyers are at the forefront of complex issues that impact financial institutions and providers of financial services in the United States and worldwide. wilmerhale.com Attorney Advertising © 2014 Wilmer Cutler Pickering Hale and Dorr llp Fire Extinguishers & Smoke Detectors Macroprudential Policy and Financial Resiliency S by R andall S. Kroszner, Professor, University of Chicago Since the global financial crisis, a debate has emerged about the appropriate role of central banks and their associated regulatory authorities in financial stability and resiliency. I believe that there are two basic views of the responsibilities: to act as a fire extinguisher or as a smoke detector. The classic role of a central bank is to act as a fire extinguisher, focusing on its ability to act as a lender of last resort and to create liquidity in times of financial stress. This role emphasizes that a central bank should stand ready to act as the flames of crisis begin to appear. It can then douse them with liquidity to prevent the flames from spreading from one institution or market to another in order to avoid a system-wide conflagration. In this view, the key responsibility is to minimize damage once the shock hits, not to foresee and prevent crisis, a goal that has been perceived as too difficult and potentially politically charged. In contrast, the smoke detector, or macroprudential, role emphasizes that a central bank has a fundamental responsibility to act early to prevent the tinder from igniting in the first place. Macroprudential policy focuses on proactive monitoring of individual institutions and interconnected markets for signs of froth and fragility. The smoke * Financial support was provided by The Clearing House. This paper draws on earlier work in Kroszner (2011 and 2012). 16 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 detector role certainly does not conflict with the more traditional fire extinguisher role but instead significantly expands the mandate and activities of regulators, supervisors, and central banks. Policymakers in the G20 and many other countries have been seeking a larger smoke detector role for central banks and regulatory authorities. Rather than take the probability of a crisis as given, or as driven primarily by factors beyond policy control, they have increased the responsibility of central banks and regulatory authorities to try to reduce the likelihood of a crisis, not just reduce the costs once the crisis hits. In this essay, I will provide a brief analysis of some of the costs and benefits of macroprudential policy and key challenges ahead. Objectives and Trade-Offs in Regulatory Reform Just as with any regulatory reform, we must articulate the objectives in order to assess the costs and benefits of macroprudential policy. The goal of banking and financial development regulation should be to support and enhance sustainable economic growth, consistent with consumer protection that maintains the integrity of the markets. A large body of research suggests that a deep and developed financial system is a driving force behind economic development and growth (see, e.g., the summaries in Levine 2005 and 2012). The evidence comes from studies of long-term growth and development across countries, as well as from studies looking across U.S. states with changing regulatory regimes (see Kroszner and Strahan 2014). In the U.S., for example, deregulation of restrictions on bank branching within and across states during the 1970s and 1980s is associated with the development of a more competitive and robust banking system and more access to credit for entrepreneurs, which increased the formation of small businesses. The international research suggests that well-developed financial systems can be particularly helpful for those at the lower end of income distribution. Increasing the efficiency of the allocation of capital to the highest return projects and giving the less affluent access to capital that they would not have in a less developed system appear to be the primary mechanisms for driving economic growth. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 17 Fire Extinguishers & Smoke Detectors: Macroprudential Policy and Financial Resiliency From a policy perspective we must ask: Could there be a trade-off between higher growth and higher volatility or potential for crises? (See Kroszner and Strahan 2011.) That is, to obtain a higher growth “return” through financial development, is there a cost in terms of greater “risk” in the system? Theoretically, greater financial depth and development could either increase or decrease stability and resiliency. On the one hand, a larger and more developed financial sector could improve risk sharing and diversification and thereby reduce volatility and increase resiliency. On the other, a larger and more developed financial sector could allow greater concentrations of risk and generate interconnections, thereby potentially making the entire system more fragile and vulnerable to shocks. Research using pre-crisis data suggests that in some circumstances a deeper financial system reduces volatility but in others can contribute to it (see, e.g., Kroszner 2007, Kroszner et al 2007, Morgan, Rime, and Strahan 2007, Arcand et al 2012, and Kroszner and Strahan 2014). The Role of Macroprudential Policy Macroprudential policy, thus, should focus on the circumstances in which financial activities may contribute to financial fragility and economic volatility. It is crucial then to assess the potential benefits of greater stability and resiliency against potential costs in terms of lower economic growth. A number of recent papers have attempted to outline such a framework (e.g., Kroszner and Strahan 2011, International Monetary Fund 2013, and Bank of England 2014), and policymakers engaged in financial regulatory reform need to consider both forces. To be able to assess the costs and benefits of macroprudential policy, it is necessary to define as clearly as possible its scope. The IMF (2013, p. 6), consistent with the Financial Stability Board and the Bank for International Settlements, describes macroprudential policy as “the use of primarily prudential tools to limit systemic risk. A central element in this definition is the notion of systemic risk—the risk of disruptions to the provision of financial services that is caused by an 18 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 impairment of all or parts of the financial system, and can cause serious negative consequences for the real economy.” This statement reflects a change from the simple fire extinguisher approach “to clean up the mess afterwards” with liquidity provision. Traditionally, it was seen as difficult to predict disruptions and to find precise tools ex ante to prevent them. This greater sensitivity to and focus on financial stability concerns is valuable, but policymakers and market participants should understand that effective macroprudential policy might not be easy. Though expanding the toolkit is valuable, I caution that there are significant challenges to implementing macroprudential supervision and regulation as an effective smoke detector, as well as political risks for the central bank. Excessive faith in macroprudential policy to stop the buildup of risk concentrations and froth in markets could lead to reduced market discipline and forms of moral hazard, so it is important to be realistic about what macroprudential policy can and cannot do. I will briefly describe three broad challenges for macroprudential policy. Three Broad Challenges for Macroprudential Policy The first broad challenge concerns data and measurement. What will be the metrics or indicators used to measure the buildup of system-wide risk and heighted vulnerability to a financial crisis that should trigger preemptive macroprudential action? Following the financial and currency crises in emerging markets in the 1980s and 1990s, academics and researchers at institutions such as the IMF and World Bank tried to develop “early warning flags” to better anticipate where and under what circumstances a crisis might occur. This exercise proved to be extremely difficult and did not produce indicators that would reliably “flash yellow” or “flash red” sufficiently far in advance to allow authorities to act to avoid trouble. Since the most recent financial crisis, the Basel Committee has emphasized rapid credit growth, either in a specific market or in an economy overall, as a warning signal. Other measures include rapid increases in asset prices, unusually compressed risk spreads, increases in leverage, and reductions in credit underwriting standards (e.g., Borio and Lowe 2002, Drehmann et al 2011, IMF 2013, and Stein 2014). These are important indicators that central banks and supervisory authorities should be monitoring. I applaud the continuing efforts to refine these “flags” but agree with the IMF (2013, p. 18) that the systemic risk monitoring framework should be characterized as a “work in progress.” Even if a reasonable set of indicators can be developed, there is a second broad challenge for macroprudential policy that is more theoretical in nature. How strong of a foundation can financial economics provide to supervisors and regulators that an asset is overpriced or a risk premium is too low? As Larry Summers (1985) emphasized many years ago, financial economics and markets are extremely good for ensuring that a 24 ounce bottle of ketchup is priced at twice as much as a 12 ounce bottle but not quite as helpful for determining what an ounce of ketchup should be worth. Assumptions about preferences, risk aversion, discount rates, liquidity, etc. are needed, and reasonable people could disagree about these. ‘‘ Distinguishing between ex ante frothiness that will end in tears and the dynamics of an evolving market economy, for example, is not straightforward. Such a distinction requires two assessments: First, what is the threshold for one or a combination of these metrics to flash yellow or flash red? Much valuable research is being undertaken to try to determine appropriate thresholds, but we are far from knowing when an economy has reached a yellow or red zone. Economies in earlier stages of development, for example, may experience more rapid credit growth than more developed economies as part of a balanced “catch-up” growth path as they converge to the more developed economies. As the IMF (2013, p. 17) has pointed out, “…not all credit booms end in a bust, as they may be justified by better fundamentals, and that loan growth can contribute to a healthy financial deepening” (see Dell’Ariccia et al, 2012). In addition, what are the system-wide consequences if the bubble does burst? (See, e.g., Mishkin 2009.) Clearly, in a market like housing that involves high leverage and that is widely used as collateral in lending, rapid asset price declines can have significant systemwide consequences, as we saw in the most recent global financial crisis. In contrast, the dramatic declines in asset values and colossal mark-to-market losses with the end of the so-called “dotcom bubble” in the early 2000s left little imprint on the macro-economy and did not trigger a banking or financial crisis. Also, new markets and instruments pose particularly vexing problems because, by their very nature, they have short data trails by which risks could be assessed. It is crucial then to assess the potential benefits of greater stability and resiliency against potential costs in terms of lower economic growth. Without a straightforward and theoretically grounded way to argue that market pricing is not properly taking a risk into account, a supervisor or regulator is open to the criticism of being arbitrary and attempting to substitute her judgment for those of the market participants who are putting their own money on the line. It can be difficult for the supervisor or regulator to prove the case. Unfortunately, this also opens the way for political judgments and pressures to determine what is and is not considered “arbitrary.” The third challenge concerns the political-economy dynamic. Will a central bank’s (or regulatory authority’s) independence be challenged if it is actively engaged in Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 19 Fire Extinguishers & Smoke Detectors: Macroprudential Policy and Financial Resiliency macroprudential policymaking? Many of the instruments of macroprudential policy involve increasing the costs of and/ or reducing the availability of credit for particular activities or to certain sectors. This can bring the central bank or supervisor into politically charged areas of credit allocation. Consider the case of housing. The U.S. and many other countries have numerous government programs and policies that encourage home ownership, ranging from reductions in down payments to subsidies, to securitization (in the U.S., for example, through the government sponsored enterprises). If a central bank becomes concerned about frothiness in housing, how easy would it be to adopt policies that reduce loan to value ratios, restrict securitization, raise capital requirements, or otherwise increase the costs of mortgages? The unelected body of the central bank could be portrayed as trying to overrule public policies explicitly adopted by an elected body. This certainly could put the central bank in the political crosshairs. Effective macroprudential policies thus may involve risks for central bank independence and the independence of supervisors. With a post-crisis mandate for a broader smoke detector, macroprudential role, central banks and associated regulatory authorities need to analyze carefully the costs and benefits of policy actions. Understanding the sources of vulnerabilities in the system is crucial to evaluating where macroprudential policy can be effective. Assuring sufficient capital through countercyclical capital buffers, for example, is quite sensible, but determining the precise level of those buffers is quite difficult. Such policies can be quite valuable but are a work in progress. We should avoid a false sense of confidence that these policies can assure stability or that we have sufficient understanding and experience to fully comprehend the trade-offs involved. References Arcand, Jean-Louis, Enrico Berkes and Ugo Panizza (2012). “Too much finance?” IMF Working Paper No. 12/161, Table 2. Bank of England, 2014. Borio, Claudio, and Philip Lowe, 2003, “Imbalances or ‘Bubbles?’ Implications for Monetary and Financial Stability,” in Asset Price Bubbles, William C. Hunter, George G. Kaufman, and Michael Pomerleano (eds.), MIT Press (Cambridge: Massachusetts). Committee on the Global Financial System, 2012, “Operationalising the Selection and Application of Macroprudential Instruments,” CGFS Papers No. 48 (Basel: Committee on the Global Financial System). Dell’Ariccia, Giovanni, Deniz Igan, Luc Laeven, and Hui Tong, with Bas Bakker and JeromeVandenbussche, 2012, “Policies for Macrofinancial Stability: How to Deal with Credit Booms,” IMF Staff Discussion Note 12/06 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Drehmann, Mathias, Claudio Borio, and K. Tsatsaronis, 2011, “Anchoring Countercyclical Capital Buffers: The Role of Credit Aggregates,” International Journal of Central Banking, Vol. 7, No. 4, December 2011. International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2013. “Key Aspects of Macroprudential Policy,” IMF Research Note, June 2013. Kroszner, Randall S., “Analyzing and Assessing Banking Crises,” speech at Federal Reserve Bank of San 20 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Francisco, Conference on the Asian Financial Crisis Revisited, September 6, 2007. Kroszner, Randall S. “Challenges for Macroprudential Supervision,” in Macroprudential Regulatory Policies: The New Road to Financial Stabilty?, Stijn Claessens, Douglas Evanoff, George Kaufman, and Laura Kodres., eds., Hackensack, NJ: World Scientific Publishers, 2011, pp, 379-86. Kroszner, Randall S. “Stability, Growth, and Regulatory Reform,” in Financial Stability Review: Public Debt, Monetary Policy, and Financial Stability, Banque de France, Paris, April 2012, pp. 87-93. Kroszner, Randall S. and Strahan, Philip E. “Regulation and Deregulation of the U.S. Banking Industry: Causes, Consequences, and Implications for the Future,” with Philip Strahan, in Nancy Rose, ed., Studies in Regulation, Chicago: NBER and University of Chicago, 2014, pp.485-543. Kroszner, Randall S. and Robert Shiller. 2011. Reforming U.S. Financial Regulation: Before and Beyond Dodd-Frank, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Levine, Ross. 2005. “Finance and Growth: Theory and Empirics.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, eds.: Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf. Kroszner, Randall S., Luc Laeven, and Daniela Klingebiel. 2007. “Banking Crises, Financial Dependence, and Growth.” Journal of Financial Economics, April, 84(1), 187-228. Levine, Ross. 2011. “Regulating Finance and Regulators to Promote Growth,” in Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Symposium on Achieving Maximum Long-Run Growth, pp. 271-312. Kroszner, Randall S. and William Melick, ““The Response of the Federal Reserve to the Recent Banking and Financial Crisis” in Jean Pisani-Ferry, Adam Posen, and Fabrizio Saccomanni, eds., An Ocean Apart? Comparing Transatlantic Response to the Financial Crisis, Brussels: Bruegel Institute and Peterson Institution for International Economics, 2011. Mishkin, Frederick. 2011. “Monetary Policy Strategy: Lessons from the Crisis,” in M. Jarocinski, F. Smets, and C. Thimann (eds.), Monetary Policy Revisited: Lessons from the Crisis, proceedings of the Sixth ECB Central Banking Conference, Frankfurt: ECB, pp. 67-118. Kroszner, Randall S. and Strahan, Philip E. “Financial Regulatory Reform: Challenges Ahead,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, May 2011, 101(3), pp. 242-46, Stein, Jeremy C. 2014. “Incorporating Financial Stability Considerations into a Monetary Policy Framework, Speech at the International Research Forum on Monetary Policy, Washington, D.C. March 21, 2014. Summer, Larry. 1985. “On Economics and Finance,” Journal of Finance, vol 40, no, 3, July, pp. 633-5. MANY INDUSTRIES, ONE FOCUS: IP Intellectual Property protects the innovations behind your new products and services. It’s also our sole focus. NEW YORK www.fitzpatrickcella.com WASHINGTON CALIFORNIA Macroeconomic Modeling and Financial Stability Lessons from the Crisis S by A ndrew W. Lo, Professor, MIT Since the Financial Crisis of 2007–2008, macroeconomic modeling has come under fire for the spectacular failure of macroprudential policies to anticipate the impact of crisis on the real economy. Guided by highly sophisticated mathematical models known as dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models, central bankers and regulators had no idea that the financial-market tremors that began as early as 2005 would exact such an enormous toll on real output and employment just a few years later. Part of the reason was, of course, the fact that the DSGE models used by central bankers did not contain a financial sector. From a macroeconomist’s perspective, financial markets are a sideshow, always operating flawlessly and without constraints to facilitate production, real investment, and economic growth. With the benefit of hindsight, we now understand that financial constraints can become extraordinarily important when market dislocation strikes. Apparently, financial stability cannot be taken for granted. The reaction against DSGE models has been swift, with the most severe critics arising from inside the economics profession. In his testimony before the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Science and Technology, MIT economist and Nobel Laureate Robert Solow leveled the following critique against this literature:1 1 22 Solow (2010, p. 2). Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 “Especially when it comes to matters as important as macroeconomics, a mainstream economist like me insists that every proposition must pass the smell test: does this really make sense? I do not think that the currently popular DSGE models pass the smell test. They take it for granted that the whole economy can be thought about as if it were a single, consistent person or dynasty carrying out a rationally designed, long-term plan, occasionally disturbed by unexpected shocks, but adapting to them in a rational, consistent way. I do not think that this picture passes the smell test. The protagonists of this idea make a claim to respectability by asserting that it is founded on what we know about microeconomic behavior, but I think that this claim is generally phony. The advocates no doubt believe what they say, but they seem to have stopped sniffing or to have lost their sense of smell altogether.” In a surprisingly frank and courageous mea culpa, Narayana Kocherlakota, President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, acknowledged the limitations of macroeconomic theory and policy:2 “I believe that during the last financial crisis, macroeconomists (and I include myself among them) failed the country, and indeed the world. In September 2008, central bankers were in desperate need of a playbook that offered a systematic plan of attack to deal with fast-evolving circumstances. Macroeconomics should have been able to provide that playbook. It could not. Of course, from a longer view, macroeconomists let policymakers down much earlier, because they 2 Kocherlakota (2010, p. 5). Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 23 Macroeconomic Modeling and Financial Stability: Lessons from the Crisis did not provide policymakers with rules to avoid the circumstances that led to the global financial meltdown.” A Brief History of Macro Policy Models These devastating indictments of a large swath of modern macroeconomics and policy is hard to square with all the Nobel prizes awarded to the architects of the influential DSGE edifice: Lucas, Kyland, Prescott, Sargent, Sims, and Hansen. Could it be that so many people were so easily fooled for so long, or has the pendulum swung too far the other way? Macroeconomic modeling for policy purposes is a relatively new endeavor. The Dutch economist Jan Tinbergen published the first empirical macroeconomic model of an economy in 1936, intended to forecast the economic effects of Dutch policy responses to the Great Depression. However, Tinbergen’s model is more than a historical footnote. Although his model was primitive by modern standards, it was the first in a lineage of macroeconomic forecasting models that are still used today.3 ‘‘ From a macroeconomist’s perspective, financial markets are a sideshow, always operating flawlessly and without constraints to facilitate production, real investment, and economic growth. In this article, I hope to shed some light on this conundrum by tracing the origins of DSGE models and asking what lessons we have learned about macroeconomic modeling from the Financial Crisis. The superficially damning criticism of the DSGE framework belies the importance of the notion of general equilibrium and the Lucas critique to macroeconomic policy, and may divert attention from the more urgent task of developing better alternatives for regulators and policymakers. By examining the historical roots of DSGE models and studying their strengths and weaknesses from a financial-markets perspective, we can see a clearer path for building the next generation of macroeconomic policy models. 24 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Tinbergen’s original approach was ad hoc, without a strong theoretical basis. Structural relationships between economic variables were eyeballed from linear regressions4 on minimal econometric data. Because the modern system of national accounts was not developed until after World War II, important macroeconomic variables were omitted from Tinbergen’s model. Nevertheless, Tinbergen’s work was striking enough to form the basis for the first generation of postwar macroeconomic models. Following the war, the late Lawrence Klein, then a young economist with the Cowles Commission, combined Tinbergen’s framework with elements of John Maynard Keynes’ macroeconomic theory to model the prewar American economy.5 Klein’s approach had two great early successes. His first model successfully predicted that the end of the war would result in a boom, not a return to the Depression-era conditions feared by many policymakers. On the other hand, an updated model, which Klein developed with Arthur Goldberger, 3 Dhaene and Barten (1989); Tinbergen (1937); Tinbergen (1981). 4 In statistics, a regression analysis is an econometric tool prominently used for investigating the relationships between variables. Typically, the investigator seeks to ascertain the causal effect of one variable for another. This requires that the investigator assemble data on underlying variables in question and use regression to determine the approximate quantitative effect of the causal variables upon the variables they influence. Investigators generally assess the degree to which the regression instills confidence in the results by assessing “statistical significance.” 5 Klein (1950). predicted that the Korean conflict would end in a recession, which also came to pass.6 These predictive successes, made against prevailing economic opinion, cemented Klein’s approach in the minds of economists and policymakers alike. Klein’s models were theoretically and statistically much more sophisticated than Tinbergen’s early efforts, and correspondingly more influential. In the late 1960s, Klein’s ambitious Brookings model inspired the Federal Reserve Board to develop its own macroeconomic model to use in forecasting and policy analysis.7 Franco Modigliani of MIT, Albert Ando of the University of Pennsylvania, and Frank de Leeuw of the Federal Reserve Board led the project to develop the MPS model (an acronym for MIT/Pennsylvania/SSRC, which funded Ando), which the Fed used from 1970 to 1995. A hallmark of the Tinbergen-Klein school of modeling was the use of a multitude of empirically derived behavioral equations to specify relationships between macroeconomic variables. For example, the original MPS model had sixty behavioral equations, a third of them having to do with the housing and mortgage market. Unexpected macroeconomic events, such as the oil shocks of the 1970s, induced modelers to add highly specific equations to model previously unforeseen linkages, such as ones for domestic coal consumption, or dummy variables for automobile and dock strikes.8 However, one macroeconomic event of the 1970s struck at the heart of the modelers’ basic assumptions. Most of these models included the inverse relationship between unemployment and inflation known as the Phillips curve.9 Although this was an empirical result, it fit the Keynesian macroeconomic framework very well, and the Phillips curve quickly became part of the standard toolkit of the postwar generation of macroeconomists. 6 Klein and Goldberger (1955). 7 Brayton et al (1997). 8 Brayton and Mauskopf (1985). 9 Phillips (1958). Unfortunately, the American economy during the 1970s demonstrated that Phillips curve was not an immutable natural law at all, but an apparent statistical fluke. The 1970s were a time of stagflation, stagnant economic growth and high inflation. Rising inflation did nothing to alleviate high unemployment in the 1970s. Central bankers who relied too much on expanding the money supply to stimulate the economy found themselves stimulating inflation instead. Enter the Lucas Critique The collapse of the Phillips curve, and the apparent failure of Keynesian macroeconomics to predict it, became an important battleground in the rational expectations revolution of the next decade. Robert Lucas was foremost among these intellectual combatants. His key insight, first published in 1976, was that economic modelers had no privileged insights into the functioning of the economy that the market did not already share. In fact, according to Lucas, the more successful an economic model was in the short run, the more likely it would fail in the long run. This stochastic drift in the quality of long-term prediction was the consequence of economic agents taking into account the changes suggested by the models. Standard econometric models failed in the long run precisely because people adapted to new economic conditions.10 This paradox became known as the Lucas critique, and it represented an existential threat to the entire postwar program of economic modeling. Any model that narrowly used historical macroeconomic data to evaluate policy was, according to Lucas, flawed at its foundation. Lucas was well aware that his conclusion was “destructive,” almost nihilistic, but he offered economists a way out from this dilemma. A macroeconomic model, to escape the Lucas critique, should consist of economic agents responding to policy changes or outside shocks according to their economic preferences. These agents would then adapt to change by following their economic self-interest. This type of model, Lucas believed, with 10 Lucas (1976). Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 25 Macroeconomic Modeling and Financial Stability: Lessons from the Crisis strong microfoundations based on the preferences of the agents themselves, rather than on empirical relationships between macroeconomic variables, would be able to avoid the problems of his critique. The Birth of DSGE The DSGE model satisfied Lucas’s criteria. Within a forward-looking, rational expectations framework, a DSGE model was populated by agents that optimized their economic choices according to their preferences, in order to find a full equilibrium solution to the general (albeit simplified) economy. Rather than focusing on static snapshots of the economy, a DSGE model allowed economic variables to change dynamically over time in a logically consistent manner. A DSGE model could also respond to random stochastic shocks, such as fluctuations in prices like the oil shocks of the 1970s, changes in policymaking, or the adoption of new technologies by economic agents. In theory, this flexibility allowed a DSGE model to be used in previously unencountered economic conditions, without having to specify new relationships in the manner of earlier macroeconomic forecasting models. DSGE models were originally associated with real business cycle (RBC) theory, which held that expansions and recessions in an economy were principally the result of outside shocks rather than changes in money supply or aggregate demand. In 1982, Finn Kydland and Edward C. Prescott found that a simple growth model, when fitted into a DSGE framework, could fit the business cycles of the postwar United States rather well. According to Kydland and Prescott’s model, technology shocks in the postwar period accounted for half the ‘action’ in U.S. business cycles. 11 For many macroeconomists, the success of Kydland-Prescott and its follow-ups validated RBC theory. Older schools of macroeconomic thought, such as classic Keynesianism or monetarism, were seen as fundamentally flawed since they could not be formulated in terms of microfoundations with optimizing agents. These early DSGE models left little room for the traditional role of fiscal and monetary policy to guide an economy. In part, this represented the modelers’ tendency to shave with Occam’s razor. If the inclusion of money or a financial sector in a model was not necessary to describe the data, they shaved it off. For many, however, this modeling decision was due to skepticism about the role of a central bank or a government in a macroeconomy. If one believes the business cycle is caused by technological shocks, as in RBC theory, one will downplay the role of central bank intervention in mediating the business cycle. Nevertheless, an opposing school, the New Keynesians, began using the DSGE microfoundational framework while incorporating Keynesian concepts such as wage and price stickiness to model the macroeconomy, allowing greater room for the role of government stabilization in these models. Academic macroeconomic modeling diverged from the models used by policymakers for a generation. For example, the Federal Reserve Board’s current model of the U.S. economy, called FRB/US, was adopted in 1995, but it is still of the highly parameterized Tinbergen-Klein lineage. Its developers conceded the importance of the Lucas critique, but they did not consider it foundational. As a result, FRB/US allows the modeler to use rational expectations, but as a secondary option in forecasting. One can direct an agent to use model-consistent future expectations, in the manner of a rational expectations model, or to limit and lag what knowledge is available to the agent.12 DSGE Goes Abroad However, the continued success and increasing sophistication of DSGE models in academia caused policymakers to take a second look at their usefulness. In 2003, the European Central Bank (ECB) released its influential DSGE model of the eurozone, devised by Frank Smets of the ECB and Raf Wouters of the National Bank of Belgium.13 In its original form, Smets-Wouters 12 Brayton, Laubach, and Reifschneider (2014). 11 Kydland and Prescott (1982). 26 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 13 Smets and Wouters (2003). operated at a very high level of abstraction. It did not model individual countries or regions or markets or industries within the eurozone. As in many earlier DSGE models, Smets-Wouters also did not incorporate an explicit role for money and financial markets. Rather, it included a “Taylor rule” to simulate the behavior of a central bank. Meanwhile, the role of the government in Smets-Wouters was quite simple: it had the power to tax and the power to adjust interest rates. model, commissioned its SIGMA model for use in policy analysis in 2006.18 By 2008, the macroeconomist Michael Woodford could tell his colleagues at the January annual meeting of the American Economics Association, “It is now accepted that macroeconomic models should be general equilibrium models.”19 ‘‘ Despite these deficiencies, the Smets-Wouters model was considered a success. Smets-Wouters fit the historical macroeconomic data of the eurozone well, including gross domestic product, consumption, investment, wages, employment, and short-term interest rates. Moreover, it outperformed vector autoregression models on the same data. With a very small number of variables, Smets-Wouters managed to describe the macroeconomic behavior of one of the most complicated economic regions in the world—and it did so better than its competition. The Smets-Wouters model would become a workhorse for the ECB. Smets-Wouters was simpler and apparently more powerful than the highly specified, almost baroque models of the Tinbergen-Klein tradition. It used the fundamental economic principle that agents would always try to optimize their behavior, subject to their constraints and preferences, to overcome the Lucas critique. Other central banks and international financial institutions quickly followed the ECB in adopting DSGE models for policy use: the International Monetary Fund and its Global Economic Model (GEM)14; the Bank of England Quarterly Model (BEQM)15; the Bank of Canada and its Terms of Trade Economic Model (ToTEM)16; and the Riksbank Aggregate Macromodel for Studies of the Economy of Sweden (RAMSES).17 Even the Federal Reserve Board of the United States, with its fantastically detailed, institutionally tested FRB/US 14 Bayoumi (2004). Macroeconomic risks must be modeled more accurately and monitored more regularly, and traditional macroeconomic forecasting models may simply lack the necessary resolution to capture modern financial crises in the making. DSGE Models and the Financial Crisis Macroeconomic crises have consistently inspired economists to create new predictive models. The Great Depression motivated Jan Tinbergen to invent a new form of macroeconomic model from scratch, while World War II impelled Lawrence Klein to synthesize Tinbergen and Keynes to create a new school of macroeconomic modeling. The macroeconomic crises of the 1970s made Robert Lucas’s critique of those models urgent and compelling, while Lucas’s insights into rational expectations made the new paradigm of the DSGE model possible. Perhaps necessity is indeed the mother of invention. 15 Harrison et al (2005). 16 Murchison and Rennison (2006). 18 Erceg et al (2006). 17 Adolfson et al (2007). 19 Woodford (2009). Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 27 Macroeconomic Modeling and Financial Stability: Lessons from the Crisis Today we live in the aftermath of the worst global financial crisis since the Great Depression. No economic model predicted the crisis or its extent beforehand. However, DSGE models came under especially harsh criticism, since many models then in use were too weakly specified to be useful for policymakers in a financial crisis. The financial crisis was transmitted through structural linkages of a sort omitted as unnecessary by DSGE modelers. Some DSGE models omitted a financial sector entirely. While other DSGE models did incorporate financial frictions, the complex range and rich variety of financial instruments were reduced to one or two assets trading in a single market. The many possible roles of a monetary authority were usually simulated by a simple Taylor rule on the interest rate. The crisis had widely different effects among populations with different financial characteristics, such as wealth and income; however, some DSGE models avoided this heterogeneity as too difficult to calculate, in favor of unitary agents representing, e.g., all the households in the economy. 20 ‘‘ The financial crisis was transmitted through structural linkages of a sort omitted as unnecessary by DSGE modelers. Some DSGE models omitted a financial sector entirely. 28 with rational expectations. For example, unemployment can be included in a DSGE model, but the premises of the DSGE framework imply that the optimizing agent somehow prefers being unemployed. DSGE models rely on exogenous shocks to drive significant changes in the macroeconomy, but these shocks—to the technological frontier, to the depreciation rate, to the labor market’s willingness to work—made little contextual sense. To quote Narayana Kocherlakota, “Why should everyone want to work less in the fourth quarter of 2009? What exactly caused a widespread decline in technological efficiency in the 1930s?”21 However, in the aftermath of the financial crisis and its illustration of “the madness of crowds,” it was the impossibility of irrational behavior within DSGE models that struck many critics as a fatal flaw. The Future of DSGE Just as the Depression and its aftermath inspired Tinbergen and Klein, and the crises of the 1970s inspired Lucas, Kydland, and Prescott, the current macroeconomic moment now appears ripe for a shift in how we think about modeling the economy. One approach, which appears to have been adopted by the Federal Reserve Board, is to downplay the importance of the Lucas critique in macroeconomic modeling, as witnessed by its aggressive use of the FRB/US model in policy analysis. However, most macroeconomists believe that the Lucas critique still holds, and that strong microfoundations are a necessity for a successful macroeconomic model. Kocherlakota (2010) presents an eloquent and inspiring overview of the current state of macroeconomics and several promising directions for the future. Let me add to his vision by suggesting two incremental shifts, and one radical shift in how we might approach this challenge. Another critique of DSGE models that emerged after the crisis regarded their lack of behavioral realism. Important economic phenomena, such as unemployment and asset bubbles, were harder to understand within a DSGE framework, which assumed optimizing agents The first shift is to take risk seriously in macroeconomic models and incorporate individual, institutional, and regulatory responses to changing risks—both real and perceived—in their decisions. We measure many aspects of our macroeconomy 20 Kocherlakota (2010), pp. 12-16. 21 Kocherlakota (2010), p. 16 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Capital strength is the foundation of our success At UBS, we are proud of our financial strength, having achieved a 13.7%* Swiss SRB Basel III CET1 capital ratio in 3Q14—the highest among our peers. Drawing on our more than 150-year heritage, we serve private, institutional and corporate clients worldwide, as well as retail clients in Switzerland. Our business strategy is centered on our preeminent global wealth management businesses and our leading universal bank in Switzerland, complemented by our Global Asset Management business and our Investment Bank. And we are committed to a culture of excellence across our firm that is focused on building a sustainable business for our stakeholders. ubs.com *As of 9.30.14, fully applied. UBS AG’s BIS Basel III common equity Tier 1 (CET1) capital ratio equals Swiss systemically relevant banks (SRB) Basel III CET1 capital ratio. For UBS AG, the Basel III framework came into effect on 1.1.13. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 © UBS 2014. All rights reserved. 29 Macroeconomic Modeling and Financial Stability: Lessons from the Crisis such as inflation, output, and unemployment but we currently have no measure of aggregate risk in the economy. Macroeconomic risks must be modeled more accurately and monitored more regularly, and traditional macroeconomic forecasting models may simply lack the necessary resolution to capture modern financial crises in the making. A broader set of measures, including those that focused on patterns in financial linkages, may be more appropriate to act as early warning indicators.22 These risk models would complement standard macroeconomic forecasts the way the National Weather Service provides real-time monitoring and active alerts— hurricanes, tornadoes, and floods cannot be legislated away but our early warning system has greatly reduced property damage and the number of lives lost. The second shift is to incorporate the financial sector more fully into existing DSGE models. It may be that the financial crisis simply came too soon in the development of DSGE modeling for it to have reached its full utility. One promising approach, following Simon Gilchrist, has been to introduce a financial accelerator to amplify the effect of shocks to the credit market on the general economy.23 A calibrated DSGE model that includes the financial accelerator can successfully account for the overall drop in economic activity during the crisis period, as well as the dramatic increase in credit spreads. A richer, more robust description of financial markets is needed. The third shift, and the most radical, is to reexamine the microfoundations of the DSGE model. Instead of agents that optimize their behavior according to rational expectations, we should consider agents with predictable irrationalities in their behavior—investor psychology, for example. Just as the optimizing behavior and rational expectations of agents in a standard DSGE model are analogous to the Efficient Markets Hypothesis, the adaptive behavior of agents in this variation have their parallels in the Adaptive Markets Hypothesis.24 These 22 Billio, Getmansky, Lo, and Pelizzon (2012), Bisias, Flood, Lo, Valavanis (2012). 23 Gilchrist and Zakrajšek (2011). 24 Lo (2004, 2012). 30 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 agents would fulfill the spirit of the Lucas critique by adapting to economic circumstance, not necessarily in an optimal way, but subject to the past environment of the agent. Macroeconomic models need to take into account Keynes’ infamous animal spirits as well as economic rationality. The assumption that aggregate behavior in an economy is approximated by optimizing, forwardlooking behavior should have been put to rest by the Financial Crisis, if not the housing bubble, or the dotcom bubble, or the Dutch tulip bubble in the mid-1600s. Optimization holds one great virtue for the modeler: it is mathematically precise. However, complexity and psychology are two sides of the same coin. Can the full complexity of the macroeconomy be captured in the behavior of precise optimizing agents, or will disasters like the recent crisis continue to emerge just beyond the grasp of our models? When Albert Einstein was criticized for the complexity of his theory of relativity, he responded that “A theory should be as simple as possible, but no simpler.” The same applies to theories of the macroeconomy. We may discover, as Keynes did over half a century ago, that from a policy perspective, being precisely wrong is not as helpful as being approximately right.25 25 Research Support from the MIT Laboratory for Financial Engineering is gratefully acknowledged. I thank Bob Chakravorti and Clark Peterson for helpful comments and Jayna Cummings and Carlos Yu for editorial and research assistance. The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the authors only, and do not necessarily represent the views and opinions of any institution or agency, any of their affiliates or employees, or any of the individuals acknowledged above. References Adolfson, Malin, Stefan Laséen, Jesper Lindé, and Mattias Villani. 2007. “RAMSES: A New General Equilibrium Model for Monetary Policy Analysis.” Sveriges Riksbank Economic Review 2, 5-40. Bayoumi, Tamim. 2004. GEM: A New International Macroeconomic Model. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund. Billio, Monica, Mila Getmansky, Andrew W. Lo, and Loriana Pelizzon. 2012. “Econometric measures of connectedness and systemic risk in the finance and insurance sectors.” Journal of Financial Economics 104, 535–559. Bisias, Dimitrios, Mark Flood, Andrew W. Lo, and Stavros Valavanis, 2012. “A survey of systemic risk analytics.” Annual Review of Financial Economics 4, 255–296. Dhaene, Geert and Anton P. Barren. 1989. “When it all began: The 1936 Tinbergen model revisited.” Economic Modelling 6, 203-219. Erceg, Christopher J., Luca Guerrieri, and Christopher Gust. 2006. “SIGMA: a new open economy model for policy analysis.” International Journal of Central Banking 2, 111-144. Gilchrist, Simon and Egon Zakrajšek. 2011. “Monetary Policy and Credit Supply Shocks.” IMF Economic Review 59, 195–232. Harrison, Richard, Kalin Nikolov, Meghan Quinn, Gareth Ramsay, Alasdair Scott and Ryland Thomas. 2005. Bank of England Quarterly Model. London: Bank of England. Klein, Lawrence Robert. 1950. Economic Fluctuations in the United States, 1921-1941. New York: Wiley. Brayton, Flint and Eileen Mauskopf. 1985. “The Federal Reserve Board MPS quarterly econometric model of the US economy.” Economic Modeling 2, 170-292. Klein, Lawrence Robert, and Arthur Stanley Goldberger. 1955. An Econometric model of the United States 1929-1952. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company. Brayton, Flint, Andrew Levin, Ralph Tryon, and John C. Williams. 1997. “The evolution of macro models at the Federal Reserve Board.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 47, 43-81. Kocherlakota, Narayana. 2010. “Modern Macroeconomic Models as Tools for Economic Policy.” The Region (May), 5–21. Brayton, Flint, Thomas Laubach, and David Reifschneider. 2014. “The FRB/US Model: A Tool for Macroeconomic Policy Analysis.” FEDS Notes. http://www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/notes/ feds-notes/2014/a-tool-for-macroeconomic-policyanalysis.html Lo, Andrew W. 2012. “Adaptive Markets and the New World Order.” Financial Analysts Journal 68, 18–29. Lucas, Robert E. 1976. “Econometric policy evaluation: a critique.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 1, 19-46. Murchison, Stephen and Andrew Rennison. 2006. “ToTEM: The Bank of Canada’s new quarterly projection model.” Bank of Canada Technical Report No. 97. Phillips, A. W. 1958. “The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957.” Economica 25, 283-299. Smets, Frank and Raf Wouters. 2003. “An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1, 1123-1175. Solow, Robert M. 2010. “Building a Science of Economics for the Real World.” Prepared Statement for House Committee on Science and Technology, Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight. Tinbergen, Jan. 1937. An Econometric Approach to Business Cycle Problems. Paris: Hermann. Kydland, Finn E. and Edward C. Prescott. 1982. “Time to build and aggregate fluctuations.” Econometrica 50, 1345-1370. Tinbergen, Jan. 1981. “The Use of Models: Experience and Prospects.” American Economic Review 77, 17-22. Lo, Andrew W. 2004. “The Adaptive Markets Hypothesis.” Journal of Portfolio Management 30, 15–29. Woodford, Michael. 2009. “Convergence in Macroeconomics: Elements of the New Synthesis.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1, 267-279. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 31 State of Banking Paul Saltzman interviews Bank of America Chairman and CEO Brian Moynihan, who discusses the opportunities facing the banking industry, his new role as Chairman of The Clearing House, and the implications of technology growth on cybersecurity, payments, and bank business models. Brian, congratulations on becoming the 78th Chairman of The Clearing House. Let’s start with some big questions. What are the opportunities facing the banking industry today and how can they be achieved? The opportunity is to deliver on what our customers and clients need and help make their financial lives better. As an industry, we’ve made progress over the past several years to become less complex, to get rid of activity that wasn’t really serving customers, and to focus on what our customers really want. By being more straightforward and better serving our customers, there’s a lot of opportunity for growth. What are your thoughts about the role of The Clearing House in our industry, and what’s on your agenda as chairman for 2015? The Clearing House serves an important role providing substantive information and rigorous analysis of issues to help policymakers make informed decisions, and that’s something I know will continue. In addition, the work The Clearing House is doing to help drive the 32 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 digital economy is important as our industry continues to improve the customer experience around payments. Building a real-time payment system will provide a level of convenience and security our customers want and that’s one goal I hope we can make progress on this next year. When you look around the world for economic growth, the U.S. looks to be in pretty good shape right now. When it comes to global and U.S. growth, what are some bright spots that you see, and what are some of the things that concern you? Globally, there is variation by region in terms of growth, but our experts say that, on the whole, GDP looks likely to finish slightly higher than last year at 3.1%. In the U.S., the good news is that underlying growth has continued to improve. The housing recovery remains on track, albeit gradual, job growth remains solid, and the corporate sector is in good health with strong balance sheets. As a company, we serve one in two American households, so we have good insight on the consumer, and the data has been pretty consistent. Brian Moynihan Chairman and Chief Executive Officer of Bank of America Corp. ‘‘ As an industry, we’ve made progress over the past several years to become less complex, to get rid of activity that wasn’t really serving customers, and to focus on what our customers really want. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 33 State of Banking Spending is up about 5% from last year and the drop in gas prices will be a further boost. So, there is a lot to be optimistic about. On a related point, what concerns you about maintaining the safety and soundness of the payments system? In many of these interviews, we talk a lot about leadership and how important leadership is in a unique industry like banking. Tell me a little bit about your views on leadership from your time leading Bank of America through some challenging times. As the payments system has changed – from cash to checks to credit cards to digital – security continues to be the industry’s first priority. What’s encouraging is that the system gets more secure with more innovation and technical advancement. The EMV and tokenization technology are good examples, and we’re always working on ways to improve. It was important that we set a clear strategy – a strategy that we are going to be customer-driven in everything we do and if we were in activities that customers did not need us to be in, we aren’t going to do it. You set that strategy and then empower the team to drive and deliver it. Banking is all about people – so equally important is creating a culture of diversity and inclusion where everyone feels they can succeed. Taking care of your employees, empowering your team and having a clear strategy – all of that is leading to better outcomes for the customers and clients we serve and better results for our shareholders. Technology is changing banking and payments as it has done in so many other industries. We’re doing things from our phones that only a few years ago required a trip to a branch. At the same time, though, banking is a relationship business and a trust business. How can banks build and maintain brands when channels are becoming digitized? Our company has one of the largest digital banking platforms with 30 million online banking customers and more than 16 million mobile banking customers. The number of new mobile customers is growing at a rate of 195,000 per month. Even so, branches remain important because banking is still very much a relationship business. The change in customer behavior and greater acceptance of technology has enabled us to optimize our banking centers. For instance, we have put more specialists in the banking centers: small business bankers, mortgage loan officers and financial services advisors, to help customers with more complex financial needs and to build on the relationships. 34 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 The next question, of course, has to do with cybersecurity—just a huge issue that’s being discussed at the very highest levels of government and industry. Where are we at on this issue, and where are we going, as both an industry and as a nation? We live so much of our lives digitally now – cybersecurity is mission critical, not just for us, but for most companies operating in the world today, and certainly for our customers and clients, too. Our job is to commit the talent and resources necessary to make our systems as secure and resilient as we can so that we can all continue to do business with confidence, whether in our local communities or around the world. We are working with partners across industries and governments to build on that commitment. What’s your strategy for Bank of America in five or ten years? What changes, and what stays the same? We have a clear purpose to help make financial lives better for those we serve, through the power of every connection we can help them make. That purpose has guided us over the past several years to make our company simpler, stronger, and more customer-focused. Our strategy is to connect all the capabilities we have and deliver the breadth of that to every single customer to help them achieve their goals. And, I believe that strategy will be the same five, ten, fifty years from now. How we deliver products may change based on customer preferences and needs but the fundamental customerfocused strategy will remain the same. IMPACT THROUGH SPECIALIZATION Oliver Wyman is a global leader in management consulting that combines deep industry knowledge with specialized expertise in strategy, operations, risk management, and organization transformation. Visit us at www.oliverwyman.com Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 35 Too Much of a Good Thing The Implications of Higher Bank Capital Requirements B by A lexey Levkov, Senior Vice President, and Clark Peterson, Senior Vice President, The Clearing House Bank equity capital is critical to maintaining a safe and sound financial position. It is the difference between a bank’s assets and its liabilities and is a funding source that acts as a financial cushion to absorb unexpected losses at times of distress. Beyond being a cushion, capital creates a strong incentive to manage a bank in a prudent manner because bank shareholders are at risk in the event of a failure. The case for imposing capital requirements on banks rests on externalities associated with bank failure. In particular, a failure of a large bank has systemic costs that are not fully borne by the bank. These costs, among others, include disruptions in the financial markets, system-wide reduction in asset values, and losses among other market participants. The regulator’s task, through mandating higher capital requirements, is to make banks internalize the systemic costs of their potential failure and buffer the financial sector from the resulting systemic losses. In this article we analyze the costs associated with changes in capital requirements. We distinguish between equity capital and debt capital and discuss both the private and social cost of requiring banks to hold additional equity capital. In the first part of the article we discuss the cost implications of changes in the mix of equity and debt. In the second part we consider how heightened capital requirements may affect allocation of credit in the economy with potential implications for financial stability and bank intermediation activities. 36 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Our main conclusion is that when abstracting from the stylized theoretical framework, funding bank activities with equity is more expensive relative to debt. We should note that it’s certainly the case that bank equity levels can be too low. In this case, more equity would enhance market perceptions of bank safety, lower cost of capital and likely result in greater credit extension. But our read of academic literature suggests that substantial increases in equity capital requirements, both in the U.S. and elsewhere, result in reduced lending and economic growth and pushes some borrowers to seek credit from less regulated sources. This leads us to two policy recommendations. First, we encourage policymakers to balance the costs and benefits of higher capital requirements (Posner, 2014), taking into account the close link between financial stability and economic growth (Rosengren, 2011; Hanson, Kashyap, and Stein, 2011). Second, capital calibrations should incorporate various banking activities that are vital for economic growth, not just the probability of bank failure, thus emphasizing the macroprudential aspects of financial regulation (Hirtle, Schuermann, and Stiroh, 2009). Capital Structure and the Cost of Capital At the firm level, the debate over bank equity capital requirements comes down to capital structure. Managers must make choices about how best to finance their assets. Broadly speaking, banks finance their assets with a mix of debt (and deposits, a form of debt) and equity, all of which are claims to the firm’s assets. Banks secure financing in the context of competitive and economic forces, as well as regulatory requirements. Capital structure choices have significant trade-offs for companies in general and for banks in particular. Debt and equity are both sources of financing, or capital, but in the banking industry context “capital” is shorthand to refer to the firm’s equity capital. Equity is a (residual) ownership claim to a firm’s assets that adjusts in value depending on the value of cash flows that a company is able to generate from its assets. Leverage, or debt capital, involves the substitution of fixed cost debt for the residual claim of owner’s equity. Leverage increases expected return and it increases risk. Leverage Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 37 net impact on Rtax OE rdate, epends n the bcank’s psrofitability, tax rate, aeturn. nd existing cap choices can relationship hat Alt everage n operat The net impact on ROE depends n the bThe profitability, aind eoxisting tructure. In aoddition tank’s o expecting a return, equity nvestors nd creditors incur a impact cost tw hen they fainance choices can impact that return. At aan oapital perating level, the bretween an equity (ROE) depends a number of pfactor (ROE) depends a no umber factors.they Higher leverage will increase iould nterest ayme business’s assets. This ctequity ost relates to he orn isk f the oiaf nvestors ssets are financing. Ton hey cost earn r addition o expecting a rteturn, equity and careditors incur a tche h decrease on assets. Bfirms ut w it hen w ill atlso In addition to expecting a return, equity In investors and incur aa cssets. ost wBut hen hey finance will cdreditors ecrease return on it wtill also dwill ecrease t axes raeturn nd increase leverag other investments with similar risk profiles. This pportunity cost ciomprises the minimum rate et mpact OE epends on tThe bank aThe his caost elates to oTtohe risk of tThe he anssets tthey aRre fdinancing. hey c nCapital et iT ore n RfrOE depends n the ank’s ax oo rn ate, and existing capital str business’s ssets. cost relates o the business’s risk of ofthe assets. ssets tmpact hey inancing. hey cbould eprofitability, arn returns n Too aMuch ofTahis Good Thing: ThetImplications Higher Requirements the business n eeds t o e arn o n i ts a ssets t o m eet t he d emands o f i ts d ebt a nd e quity i nvestors. other investments with similar risk ptrofiles. This oIn pportunity cost comprises the m inT other investments with similar risk profiles. This opportunity ost comprises he minimum raate f rteturn o expecting return, equity In addition tco expecting a return, equity investors addition nd o creditors incur a ac ost when they ifnve ina firm’s cost othe f capital. usiness eeds tao odn its arand ssets to minvestors. f his ifts debt aTnd ecquity assets. cost relates to tould he risk the business needs to earn on its assets to mbeet the business’s dnemands oef arn its ebt equity This s the ssets. This cost elates to the reet isk otbusiness’s f he the daemands ssets tihey aoTre inancing. hey e other i nvestments w ith s imilar r isk p rofiles. firm’s c ost o f c apital. other i nvestments w ith s imilar r isk p rofiles. T his o pportunity c ost c omprises t he m inimum firm’s cost o f c apital. allows a firm to create multiple risk-returnccombinations debt and equity— A company’s ost of capital is particular known atype s its ofWcapital—both eighted Average Cost of Capital, or WACC. It states 1 the business needs to earn on its assets to m the business needs to earn on its assets to meet the demands of its debt and equity investo from any particular set of assets (Higginso2011). weighted byctheir in the company’s company’s verall cost firm’s of ost capital ics apital. the oproportion f each particular type ocapital f ocf apital—both debt and eq firm’s capital. A c ompany’s of ocf C apital if s ost kapital, nown aos iW ts Weighted Acost verage cost A company’s cost of capital is known as its Weighted Acverage ost o C r ACC. I t s tates that a Cost of Capital, or WA structure: weighted by their proportion icn ost the company’s apital company’s of cf apital iis s tkche cost sotructure: f Weeighted ach pearticular type o f capital—both company’s cost of ocf apital is ko nown as its company’s overall cost of bycapital he cofost of eon ach oA pverall articular capital—both aA nd company’s tcype ost oo cf apital nown as idts ebt Aquity— verage Cost Capital, r WACC. It W s Banks create value earningis atrate return company’s o verall c ost o f c apital i s t he c ost weighted b y t heir p roportion i n t he c ompany’s c apital s tructure: ! ! company’s o verall c ost o f c apital i s t he c ost o f e ach p articular t ype o f c apital—both d ebt a n weighted b y t heir p roportion i n t he c ompany’s c apital s tructure: their assets for equity holders, structure and capital 𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊 = 𝐾𝐾! ( ) + 𝐾𝐾! ( weighted ) by their p roportion in the compan !!! !!!capital structure: weighted b y t heir p roportion i n t he c ompany’s choices can impact that return. At an operating level, ! ! ! 𝐾𝐾 on ( ! ) 𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊 = 𝐾𝐾! ( !) + 𝐾𝐾! ( ! ) relationship leverage 𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊 = ( ) + 𝐾𝐾 the between and return equity !!! !!! ! ! ! ) times 𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊 = 𝐾𝐾 the proport This formula tells !!! us that is = its ( 𝐾𝐾 a company’s cost of capital 𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊 𝐾𝐾c!ost ( o) f +e 𝐾𝐾quity !!! ! (!!! ) !!! (ROE) depends on a number of factors.1 Higher leverage !This formula tells us that a company’s cost of capital is ) plus the c cost ocf ost debt (co𝐾𝐾apital ) times the poroportion f d! ) ebt n pro toht equity in its This capital structure ( s that times tells equity f proportion s ost ouef s quity ethat quity (o 𝐾𝐾 This fiormula tf ells a( 𝐾𝐾 company’s ciost the ormula toells s ctompany’s hat a(( 𝐾𝐾 ompany’s cost f apital is ts cco ost f !!! will increase whichcwill cost the ofiits equity in times tohe p!croportion This formula tells uinterest s that payments, a company’s ost decrease of fcormula apital This is ifts cuits ost f of eauquity ! ) times ! )) times ! ! ! ! ) plus he o increase n i(((ts capital ! pplus ost debt tquity he the proportion orf equ dtebt n its its cow apital return assets. But it willstructure( taxes capital debt ) (pilus tlus he otthe che 𝐾𝐾apital ) t imes tiimes roportion capital shtructure ( proportion ). Tand o in uoinderstand a structure dstructure ecrease n ))l everage ooequity r f oof aidf n n ihe n setructure cp(!!! apital !!))times ) plus !!! tequity he cost f ts dequity ebt (i𝐾𝐾 f ost dccost ebt tebt c𝐾𝐾 equity in its con apital structure ( also decrease !!! !!! ! ) times the ! !!! !proportion of debt in the capital structure ). Tn o increase understand how ac apital decrea increase the firms leverage multiplier. The net impact structure( ). To ). To understand a sdtability, ecrease structure( or in h equity !!! ! will affect loans rates, c!redit ethe xtension, and financial wleverage e m(ust ow hose structure( ). To u!!! nderstand how ahquity ow decrease in irn leverage our anderstand an increase in etquity c structure( ). T o u nderstand h ow a d ecrease i n l everage o r a n i ncrease i n e c apital equirements !!! on ROE understand how a decrease in aleverage oraan increase in will ffect loans wrates, credit extension, and !!! depends on the bank’s profitability, tax rate, and will a ffect l oans r ates, c redit e xtension, nd f inancial s tability, e m ust u nderstand h ow t h impact a bank’s W ACC. rates, credit extension, and financial stability, we must understand h ffect loans ahanges bank’s WACC. existing capital structure 2011). capital will affect loanscrates, credit will affect loans rates, credit (Handorf extension, awill nd fainancial stability, we ust requirements how timpact hose impact a equity bank’s Wm ACC. understand impact a bank’s Wextension, ACC. and financial stability, we must understand impact a bank’s WACC. Acquiring or holding assets requires an aessets stimation oaf n beoth their nd their risk. Banks rea Acquiring or their haolding assets requires an Becanks stim Acquiring or holding requires stimation orf eturn both return and their risk. how those changes impact a bank’s WACC. for shareholders by investing in assets—mak ‘‘ for shareholders by investing in aassets—making hloans—that ave rate of rraeturn xceeds for shareholders by irnvesting in alaoans—that ssets—making have rate of tarhat eturn that reisk xce ssets equires n erstimation of reate baoth heir eturn nd teheir Acquiring or holding assets requires an eAcquiring stimation oor f hbcolding oth their return aond their isk. Bto anks vtttractiveness alue of ccapital. Tahus, the cost oof f cn apital is used to of apital. T hus, t he c ost f c apital i s u sed a ppraise t he ew l oans t hat of capital. Tfor hus, the cost of cbapital is used to appraise the attractiveness oave f new loans trhat will s hareholders y i nvesting i n a ssets—making l oans—that h a r ate o f eturn t hg requires an estimation t heir c ost of for shareholders by investing in assets—making loans—that that exceeds h Acquiring ave a r ate or holding o f r eturn assets 1 of T 1hus, R OE ( net both income/equity) c ost R(net OE (inet income/equity) is equal its Return n ulti As of return capital uRsed too atssets, ppraise tghe attractiveness f leverage n ew looan is equal tio s ts eturn n Banks A by to to he m their their risk. create value for multiplied of capital. Thus, the cost of capital is used tco apital. appraise thich he the aquity ttractiveness oand f those niew loans hat ill ncome/assets) enerate 1 to w which quity is used finance those am ssets (assets ROE (net income/equity) is to ew qual teo its R Assets, (net income/assets) meultiplied by tto he leverage ultiplier, is eturn used to ofn inance assets (assets/equity). in assets—making loans— i s u sed t o f inance t hose shareholders a ssets ( assets/equity). by investing to w hich equity (net income/equity) s em qual to its eturn on Aexceeds ssets, (net income/assets) that ihave a rate of bRreturn their cost ROE (net income/equity) is equal to its Return on RAOE ssets, (net income/assets) ultiplied y the lthat everage multiplier, the of degree multiplied by the levera is used to finance those assets (assets/equity). The Modigliani-Miller irrelevance to w hich e quity capital. Thus, the cost of capital is used to appraise the to which equity is used to finance those assets (assets/equity). 1 1 proposition is the starting point for capital structure; it is not analyzing the ending point. In addition to expecting a return, equity investors and creditors incur a cost when they finance a business’s assets. This cost relates to the risk of the assets they are financing. They could earn returns on other investments with similar risk profiles. This opportunity cost comprises the minimum rate of return the business needs to earn on its assets to meet the demands of its debt and equity investors (Higgins 2011). This is the firm’s cost of capital. A company’s cost of capital is known as its Weighted Average Cost of Capital, or WACC. It states that a company’s overall cost of capital is the cost of each 1 38 ROE (net income/equity) is equal to its Return on Assets, (net income/assets) multiplied by the leverage multiplier, the degree to which equity is used to finance those assets (assets/equity). Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 attractiveness of new loans that will generate risky cash 2 flows. The risk-return calculation on whether to make those loans is determined by “discounting” the cash flows from the loan by the cost of capital. Thus, if a bank’s cost of capital exceeds the rate of return derived from cash flows from a new loan, the loan will not be made or the bank will increase the rate charged for the loan so that it exceeds its cost of capital. Since debt provides a fixed return and contractual certainty to the debt holder, the cost of debt is an observable data point and is simply the yield-to-maturity on the debt and other liabilities issued by the bank.2 High-grade U.S. companies, for example, issue debt at an average of approximately 5% according to historical data from public sources.3 2 This issue is much simplified for the purposes of this article. This concept is much more complex and includes estimations of debt betas, but this is beyond the scope of this article. 3 For example, according to U.S. Treasury Department HQM corporate yield curve data, the average yield-to-maturity on 10 year high-grade corporate bonds from 2009-2013 was 4.74% (monthly spot rate). <http://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/ economic-policy/corp-bond-yield/Pages/Corp-Yield-Bond-CurvePapers.aspx> their assets with a mix of debt (and deposits, a form of debt) and equity, all of which are claims to the firm’s assets. Banks secure financing in the context of competitive and economic forces, as well as regulatory requirements. Capital structure choices have significant tradeoffs for companies in general and for banks in particular. risky cash flows. The risk-‐return calculation on whether to make those loans is determined by and equity are both sources of financing, or capital, but in the banking industry context “capital” is n on whether to make Debt those ltoans is determined “discounting” he cash flows from bty he loan by the cost of capital. Thus, if a bank’s cost of capital exceeds Estimating cost of equity, residual Using formula above, we can estimate of assets shorthand refer o the irm’s eequity capital. Equity is athe (residual) ownership claim tthe o acost firm’s n fblows. y the cost risk-‐return of the capital. hus, if the at bo ctost oanf tcfcunsecured apital xceeds rate cToalculation f return dank’s from ash flows from a new the loan oerived n whether o make ty hose loans is dloan, etermined by will not be made or the bank will lation oTn he whether tclaim, o that make t hose l oans i s d etermined b is more challenging. The key is to examine the equity for an average risk company. The return on U.S. aw djusts in depending on w the alue of cash flows that a company is able to generate from its from the a new loan, the loan not by ve talue made othe r bank ill vit increase the rofill ate charged loan so Tthat its cost capital. has exceeded the risk-free lows the lhus, oan bigenerally he cfor ost oost f the cto apital. hus, if eaxceeds bank’s cost ostocks f ocf apital exceeds types risks related holding a risky common on average e ing” loan by ctash he cfost othree f fcrom apital. T f a b ank’s c o f c apital e xceeds assets. L everage, o r d ebt c apital, i nvolves t he s ubstitution o f f ixed c ost debt for the residual claim of hat it exceeds its fcrom ost ocf capital. from a new loan, 4 f return derived foan lows the loan ww ill ill not be rate made or the bank will by 6-7% (Higgins 2011). Let’s asset:tash (1) the time value ofbmoney, (2)or an inflation on government bonds ot lows from a new l oan, he l w ill n e m ade t he b ank owner’s e quity. Leverage i ncreases e xpected r eturn a nd i t i ncreases r isk. Since debt p5rovides a fixed return and contractual certainty to the debt holder, Lteverage he cost oaf llows debt ais fairm n to create he for the loan sco that it exceeds risk its premium cost of crelated apital. to premium, and (3) a firm-specific assume a market risk premium of 7%, a 3% rate on a n tractual so rtate hat cciharged t ertainty exceeds i ts c ost o f apital. to tmultiple he debt hrisk-‐return older, ost of debt arom n any particular ombinations assets Higgins 2011). issued by the observable data point athe nd cis simply the is yfield-‐to-‐maturity on stet he odf ebt and (o ther liabilities the2 riskiness of the firm’s assets (Higgins 2011). The first long-term Treasury bond, and a beta of one. The cost of eld-‐to-‐maturity on rteturn he Hdigh-‐grade ebt and other liabilities issued bxample, y tdhe bank. U.S. for tehe dcapital ebt n oaf +verage pproximately 5assumptions, % according t cpontractual rovides a fixed cdontractual certainty ebt hissue older, the act ost d1ebt is oaf =n a10%. two Banks are thecompanies, rate a c“risk-free” government isaassets 3% * (7%) Under these d certainty to aequivalent tnd he ebt tovhalue older, ton he ost too f 3 rdate ebt is aeturn n c reate b y e arning a o f r o n t heir f or e quity h olders, a nd c apital structure mple, issue debt t istorical asimply n average f from approximately 5n % the according to aihs dlong-term ata public sources. which debt for e dyata point and he yoield-‐to-‐maturity obond, ay nd other an liabilities issued by the has a cost of equity of 10%. bond, U.S. Treasury our average-risk U.S. company he ield-‐to-‐maturity ochoices n tlike he tad ebt a nd o ther l iabilities i ssued b t he can impact that return. A6t an operating level, the relationship between leverage and return on gh-‐grade U.S. companies, for ebe iisk-‐return ssue debt at 3%. an aoverage of to am % according purposes can assumed to yield about 1pproximately ash fxample, lows. n ake those leverage loans i5 etermined by r example, issue debt arisky t an a(verage of he f eraquity, pproximately 5% awccording equity ROE) oan n acalculation umber o f rhether fesidual actors. H igher will increase payments, Estimating tche oTepends u nnsecured c laim, is m ore s cdhallenging. The interest key is to examine which 3 cost d 3 data from public sources. Estimates vary, but banks haveexceeds equity betas of cal “discounting” t he c ash f lows f rom t he l oan b y t he c ost o f c apital. T hus, i f a b ank’s c ost o f c apital 4 .d r esidual claim, is tmhree ore cdypes hallenging. Tghe koey s tro examine will ecrease return n aissets. But t w ill also ad ecrease taxes and the ff irms leverage (2) am n ultiplier. the f risks elated tio haolding isky asset: (1) time vbalue m oney, 8 increase the tcan rate we of o rmeasure eturn derived from cash frisk lows premium? from new loan, trhe loan will not b1.2. e tmhe ade or the ank woill How a enerally firm-specific approximately Using the formula above, banks 4 5 (ore 2) o hthe olding ao rf isky asset: (1) he tihe time alue oney, ntet mpact on (3) RoOE dtirm-‐specific epends n atricn he bp7ank’s rofitability, rofrate, and xisting capital structure. 9 The increase rate cnd harged ff he loan so tohat t exceeds its cpost oelated f capital. o inflation premium, ravesidual aor m fis isk remium tax he iskiness f the firm’s assets. g cost equity, aThe n laim, hallenging. Trhe key o examine The risk premium beta (β). would haveits attcost equity ofeo approximately 11.5%. cured residual claim, ifirm-specific s umnsecured ore challenging. Tche kknown ey is is mtaso examine 4 risk premium to ratelated he ebeta rquivalent iskiness of ton the frirm’s ssets. first two re o tthe rate oasset: n a “(Pricing risk-‐free” government bond, l and ike f long-‐term U.S. assume Treasury 1) 4The (c2) types risks rgaelated enerally htolding ahe isky and the time vto alue f mhdeposits oney, Estimating iso based Capital Asset Including other forms debt a fixed r eturn am contractual caertainty the doebt older, the ost a on debt is an of debt, (2) n ted to o hf olding risky aSince sset: (1) pttrovides he value o rf eturn, oney, addition t o eime xpecting a.S. equity investors and creditors incur a cost when 10they finance a 6 5overnment In sk-‐free” g b ond, l ike a l ong-‐term U T reasury wobservable hich for doata ur urposes an bthe e ayssumed abanks aliabilities ppoint and is sc imply ield-‐to-‐maturity on the a3nd other issued brate y the (CAPM), which the can borrow at an average 2%. Let’s now o yield premium, and bond, (3) aModel firm-‐specific rrisk pdescribes remium related the rtiskiness obout f debt the f%. irm’s ssets. The ecific risk p remium r elated iskiness of cost the frelationship irm’s tao tssets. The 6 2to the business’s a ssets. T his r elates o t he r isk o f t he a ssets t hey a re f inancing. T hey ould earn returns on bank. H igh-‐grade U .S. c ompanies, f or e xample, i ssue d ebt a t a n a verage o f a pproximately 5 % a ccording med t o y ield a bout 3 %. between returngon any risky asset and lits put all ofUthe together to answer thecfollowing are quivalent gtovernment o the rate othe n ond, aexpected “risk-‐free” overnment breasury ond, ike a long-‐term .S. pieces Treasury 3 n a “erisk-‐free” b l ike a l ong-‐term U .S. T to w historical data from pw ublic other im nvestments ith ssources. imilar isk profit rofiles. cost cpomprises minimum rate of 7 return How can e measures easure firm-‐specific r risk The oquestion: fpportunity irm-‐specific risk remium its he known as b (β). 6ppremium? risk. Beta theato sensitivity of a firm’s to This How will requiring banks to rely more oneta 6assumed ich f or o ur p urposes c an b e y ield a bout 3 %. 7 assumed tTo yield about 3b %. pis remium The cost oo f cf apital is ebt % +a 1nd * (7%) = 10%. iU nder these aT ssumptions, an average-‐risk U.S. company o remium? he firm-‐specific reta isk itn s o kBy nown bthe eta (β).Ptricing the eeds arn oan s its meet tore he one. ikts equity nvestors. his is the Estimating business bcnased tehe Aasset (emands CAPM), ds t33escribes the rtheir elationship overall economic overall expensive equity rather costthese of assumptions, Estimating the conditions. ost of eoquity, adefinition n Cuapital nsecured rssets esidual claim, iM s model cdhallenging. ey d ithan o xamine one. The cost oTw f he chich apital is % e+debt 1 * (impact 7%) = 10%. U nder an average-‐risk U.S. company has a cost of equity of 10%. 4 has awhich ctost of vin eeasures quity of f influences 0%. set Pmricing Model (CAPM), wrchich df the he rirm-‐specific elationship 2) the an rate banks the three types ocf one. risks raelated to hone olding a a rpisky sset: (1) tB he ime alue oeta m1oney, firm’s oremium? apital. market aeost beta ofescribes Agenerally beta means capital, turn between thas he xpected return ogreater n ny than risky asset nd risk. eta m tβ). he 7s (ensitivity of a charge firm’s on 8 7 aits we easure a f irm-‐specific isk p T f r isk remium i s k nown a s b ( isk premium? The firm-‐specific risk p5remium is known raisk s bpremium eta (β).related betas of approximately 1.2. Using the formula above, banks vary, banks have equity inflation premium, saensitivity nd (3) than a firm-‐specific o Estimates the riskiness obf ut the firm’s assets. asset aind its risk. Btthat eta easures tmore he of market aCAPM), firm’s aCm company isconomic risky the awwhole, and credit profit to overall esset conditions. By dasefinition tescribes he loans otverall m hoas a bhave eta of The obne. eta greater Estimates velationship ary, availability? but banks equity etas A of b approximately 1.2.8 Using the formula above, banks g b eta s b ased o n he apital A P ricing M odel ( hich d the rarket would h ave a c ost f e quity o f a pproximately 11.5%.99 Including deposits and other forms of debt, al Asset Pricing Model A first (CAPM), w hich d escribes t he r elationship two are equivalent to ctapital he rate ios n kanown “risk-‐free” gts overnment bond, like a long-‐term Uf .S. Tapital, reasury or WACC. c ompany’s c ost o f a s i W eighted A verage C ost o C I t s tates hat a and other forms of debt, would have a cost of equity of approximately 11.5%. Including dteposits and vice versa. efinition the orverall arket hhich as tfahat eta o f one. A beta greater 6arket borrow at avn ice average rate 2 %.10 Let’s now put all of the pieces together to answer the than om m eans a pcaurposes ompany i s ore risky than mensitivity abs anks ao f wacan hole, and versa. the expected eturn one n aeta ny isky a bsset nd iensitivity ts cran isk. Bassumed eta m easures the 3s%. firm’s 10 bond, wrm or our be m to yield about assume risky asset and its risk. B easures t he s o f a f irm’s assume b anks c an b orrow a t a n a verage r ate 2 %. L et’s n ow p ut all of the pieces together to answer the verall cost of c apital is the cost of each Tofollowing particular type of wcill apital—both ebt nd on eequity— uestion: How requiring banks o rely maore xpensive equity rather than debt impact answerqthat question, we need to firsttd understand sky than the market acompany’s s a whole, aoefinition nd vice vtersa. overall e conomic c onditions. B y d he o verall m arket h as a b eta o f o ne. A b eta g following question: Hreater ow will requiring banks to rely more on expensive equity rather than debt impact 7 By definition tTherefore, he overall arket heasure quity bap eta f o) ne. A tpbhe eta greater opredicts f capital, hich in influences ate banks charge on loans and credit availability? How m an w froportion irm-‐specific riisk remium? The free firm-‐specific risk premium nown ats urn bexamine eta β). real-world weighted bmy tas n crisk ompany’s cinterest apital scctructure: kw Therefore, the cost (o𝐾𝐾 the free whattheir theory and then tche ce ost oheir f ofaeequity equals the risk rost ate n gis overnment b(onds (tthe 𝑅𝑅!rr) plus the ! ) equals their ost of o capital, w hich in turn influences he ate banks charge on loans and credit availability? means t hat a c ompany i s m ore r isky t han t he m arket a s a w hole, a nd v ice v ersa. Estimating b eta i s b ased o n t he C apital A sset P ricing M odel ( CAPM), w hich d escribes t he r elationship ore isky than the m arket a s a w hole, a nd v ice v ersa. he rrisk free interest r ate o n g overnment b onds ( 𝑅𝑅 ) p lus t he interest raterisk on government bonds plus the firmfactors may deviate from the framework. To athat nswer that T qhe uestion, we need ttheoretical o first understand what theory predicts and then examine real-‐world ! t) imes firm-‐specific p remium: b eta ( β) t he M arket R isk P remium. M arket R isk P remium i s d efined To answer t!the hat question, w e an eed to first understand what theory predicts and then examine real-‐world between the expected return on any risky asset and its risk. Beta easures sensitivity of irm’s ! mfactors m) ay deviate from tfhe theoretical ramework. that higher equity and less mprofit verall beta above 𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊𝑊 = 𝐾𝐾 ( Theory ) factors +b onds 𝐾𝐾hpredicts (tthat specific risk premium: (β) times theBMarket Risk that higher equity and less ffleverage inTTheory a ppredicts the Mcarket Reisk Premium. T he M arket R isk P remium i s d efined !rate !as hat m ay d eviate f rom t he t heoretical ramework. heory redicts that higher equity and less , t he ost o f quity ( 𝐾𝐾 ) e quals t he r isk f ree i nterest r ate o n g overnment ( 𝑅𝑅 ) p lus t he as t he arket r eturns o ver a nd t he r isk f ree 𝑅𝑅 − 𝑅𝑅 . t o o e conomic c onditions. y d efinition t he o verall m arket a b eta o f o ne. A b eta g reater !!! !!! ! rate on government bonds (𝑅𝑅 ) plus the ! !"# ! leverage i n a b ank’s c apital s tructure w ill l ower t he b ank’s b eta, w hich w ill reduce the cost of equity uals the risk free interest ! Premium. Risk Premium isore defined the capital will the bank’s which leverage astructure bvank’s capital slower tructure will lower tbeta, he bank’s beta, which will reduce the cost of equity ne eans that a company is P m risky tas han the market arket bank’s as aisk w!hole, ain nd ice vs ersa. risk rfisk ree rremium: ate 𝑅𝑅!"# − than 𝑅𝑅 .imes The mMarket (𝐾𝐾 ). Lremium everage increases b oth risk and return. Bank betas capture the risk of the bank’s assets plus the ! o ific p b eta ( β) t t he M arket R isk remium. T he M R P i d efined (𝐾𝐾 mes the Market Risk PThis remium. Tover he Market Rthe isk remium is cdost efined Leverage io ncreases both risk a). nd imes return. tBhe ank pbroportion etas capture the bank’s assets plus the market returns and above free rate will incremental reduce cost of equity formula tells us that Pcompany’s of capital i!s ). its cthe ost equity (( 𝐾𝐾 of risk of tahe risk rf elated to leverage. etas can bincreases e “unlevered and relevered” ccording to target capital ! ) tBLeverage 𝐾𝐾a) risk 𝑅𝑅!the + r 𝛽𝛽 ∗free (𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃) ! e= incremental t o l everage. B etas c an b e “ unlevered a nd r elevered” a ccording to target capital Therefore, the cost foree f equity (𝐾𝐾! 𝑅𝑅 quals isk i nterest r ate o n g overnment b onds ( 𝑅𝑅 ) p lus t he 11 risk related rket r eturns o ver a nd a bove t he r isk r ate − 𝑅𝑅 . ! !"# ! ! structure. Thus, the cost of equity will decline as a bank relies more on equity capital. Returning to e 𝛽𝛽the risk free rate ( 𝑅𝑅!"# − 𝑅𝑅in . capital structure risk (and 11 return. Bank betas capture the risk of the ! ). ∗ (𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃) ) pMlus the cost oboth f dWACC, ebt 𝐾𝐾 t imes he o f i n t he apital equity its ( the structure. )T hus, the ctost of peroportion quity will decline ad s ebt a bank relies mcore on equity capital. Returning to ! firm-‐specific risk premium: beta (β) times arket R isk P remium. T he M arket R isk P remium i s d efined even though higher bank equity capital requirements will force banks rely more on expensive !!! assets plus the hincremental riskcrelated to rleverage. WACC, even ta hough igher bank equity apital Trhe equirements Using the fhe ormula bove, we and can estimate he rcate ost 𝑅𝑅o!"# f ebank’s quity an verage risk company. eturn woill n force banks rely more on expensive ! as t= market raeturns over above the risk ftree − 𝑅𝑅! . f or equity (11.5%) than cheaper debt (2%), the cost of the equity will decline to precisely offset new capital 𝐾𝐾 𝑅𝑅 + 𝛽𝛽 ∗ (𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃) ! ! structure( ). T o u nderstand h ow a d ecrease i n l everage o r a n i ncrease i n e quity c apital equirements 𝑅𝑅 t!he +c 𝛽𝛽 ∗ (𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃) equity ( 11.5%) t han c heaper d ebt ( 2%), t he c ost o f t he erquity will 12 decline to precisely offset new capital Betas “unlevered and relevered” to ost of equity an average risk he erxceeded eturn on the risk-‐free structure eightings (see footnote for formulas and c(alculations). Of course, all things being equal, a !!! U.S. fcor ommon stocks on caompany. verage hTas rcan ate beown government bonds baccording y 6-‐7% Higgins 12 structure w eightings ( see f ootnote f or f ormulas a nd c alculations). Of course, all things being equal, a 11 𝐾𝐾 = 𝑅𝑅 + 𝛽𝛽 ∗ (𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀𝑀 𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃) ! ! less l evered b ank w ill b e a ble t o b orrow m ore c heaply t oo. target capital structure. Thus, the cost of equity will will a ffect l oans r ates, c redit e xtension, a nd f inancial s tability, w e m ust u nderstand h ow t hose c hanges ded the raisk-‐free rate o n egstimate overnment bost onds brisk y 6-‐7% (Higgins 2011). Let’s assume a m arket premium overage f 7%, ar 3isk % crate n a long-‐term reasury bond, a beta o f mate formula bove, w e c an t he c o f e quity f or a n a ompany. T o n less olevered bhe ank rweturn ill be aTble to borrow more cheaply too. the cost of equity for an average risk company. The return on decline as a bank relies more on equity capital. Returning a fbormula ank’s W an idea that the cost of eT quity declines Using the atbove, wbe ond, cto n The average company. he return on to precisely offset additional reliance on more expensive equity m of 7s%, a 3% ate o4n impact aThe hlong-‐term Treasury ar ate beta ocost f gcost timee value of money is ACC. related theestimate opportunity of of equity for mon tocks on rrisk-‐free average as xceeded he risk-‐free othe n overnment baonds by that 6risk -‐7% Higgins The idea he c(ost of equity declines to precisely offset additional reliance on more expensive equity xceeded the rU.S. ate oA n government bonds bey 6now -‐7% Higgins onceptually ound tbhigher hough subject tequity o numerous simplifying assumptions—assumptions that vary in tooWACC, even tthough bank capital money. dollar today andon a dollar a year from are t(not equal. common stocks average has xceeded he risk-‐free rate n is gcovernment bsonds y 6-‐7% (Higgins r isk A dollar p remium a year from o now is worth a 3 less r than aodollar is conceptually ound to hough subject to numerous simplifying assumptions—assumptions that vary in t’s assume a m f 7 a%, % ate n aa otoday, lbong-‐term Treasury bdoth ond, aw bshich eta f reflect because the egree t o t hey r eality. I ndeed, t he foregoing analysis took into account only the mium of 7%, a arket 32 T% r ate o n a ong-‐term T 2011). Llet’s assume mreasury arket risk bprond, remium f eta 7 %, ao stimation 3f % rate on a l ong-‐term T reasury b ond, b eta o f Acquiring o r h olding a ssets equires a n e o f b t heir r eturn a nd t heir r isk. B anks create value requirements force banks to rely more on expensive his issue much or money. the purposes this required article. This concept much ore omplex arnd includes estimations oaf nalysis the dis egree twill o m which tchey reflect eality. Indeed, the foregoing took into account only the oneis could earnsimplified interest on fthe Thus, part ooff the narrow set of factors. debt b etas, b ut t his i s b eyond t he s cope o f t his a rticle. narrow s et o f f actors. return on a risky asset is to compensate the investor for the for s hareholders b y i nvesting i n a ssets—making l oans—that h ave a r ate o f r eturn t hat e xceeds t heir c ost is article. This concept is much more complex and includes estimations of athat ccording could be t o U .S. T reasury their money. Department HQM corporate yield curve data, the average yield-‐to-‐maturity on 10 3 F or e xample, interest earned on Discussions of capital structure and corporate finance often begin with the theoretical framework of 2 le. issue is mT uch simplified the po urposes of this ias rticle. This tconcept is much mtore complex nd includes estimations of loans that will generate of Tchis apital. hus, the Tfcor ost f capital umsed o (monthly appraise he attractiveness of new Discussions caapital structure s much simplified year for the purposes corporate of this article. his concept is much complex and includes of and corporate finance often begin with the theoretical framework of high-‐grade bonds from 2009-‐2013 was 4ore .74% spot rate). eo<f stimations http://www.treasury.gov/resource-‐ & Miller (MM), which that, under certain conditions and when cash flows are held 8 Modigliani See: PWC (2013), King (2009) andshows Handorf (2011) debt etas, ut his is cbomplex eyond the snd cope of this article. nt orporate yield dbmata, average yield-‐to-‐maturity ostimations n 10 s oH f tQM his acrticle. This concept is required uch bthe mtore aasset includes einclude of 5 curve The return on any risky must also Modigliani & Miller (MM), which shows that, under certain conditions and when cash flows are held 3 but his is eyond center/economic-‐policy/corp-‐bond-‐yield/Pages/Corp-‐Yield-‐Bond-‐Curve-‐Papers.aspx> the scope his corporate yield curve constant, data, the atverage y ield-‐to-‐maturity on 10 carries has no effect on its value. Capital structure is irrelevant he amount of debt a company compensation F oor f < e thttp://www.treasury.gov/resource-‐ xample, a rticle. a to ccording the investor t o U .S. for T reasury loss D ofepartment purchasing HQM as 4t.74% monthly s pot r ate). s article. (b the power over 4 the amount of 1(including ebt a company carries has no effect on its value. Capital structure is irrelevant 9ate). 3% 1.2*(7%) = a11.5% some rounding). 1 year high-‐grade corporate belated onds rom 2t009-‐2013 was 4.74% spot < http://www.treasury.gov/resource-‐ le, according U.S. Treasury D QM corporate yield curve data, he verage yconstant, ield-‐to-‐maturity oiultiplied n The MM framework llustrates aban pn oint: ost ncot ompanies reate value by managing their The time vlife alue o f d m oney is arverage he c(monthly ost of am oney. d+ollar today nd a dd0 ollar ear rom ow aultiplier, re the ROE (net income/equity) ifs qual too pportunity its Return o n A ssets, (rnet iAncome/assets) m y yitmportant he lfeverage mm the dcegree p-‐Yield-‐Bond-‐Curve-‐Papers.aspx> of the investment. artment HQM to corporate yield cepartment urve ata, tH he yeto ield-‐to-‐maturity on 1t0 center/economic-‐policy/corp-‐bond-‐yield/Pages/Corp-‐Yield-‐Bond-‐Curve-‐Papers.aspx> M M framework illustrates an important point: most companies create value by managing their The ade c orporate b onds f rom 009-‐2013 w as 4 .74% ( monthly s pot r ate). < http://www.treasury.gov/resource-‐ 42ollar equal. A d a y ear f rom n ow i s w orth l ess t han a d ollar t oday, b ecause o ne c ould e arn i nterest o n t he m oney. T hus, p art o f to w hich e quity i s u sed t o f inance t hose a ssets ( assets/equity). 10 Elliot (2013) uses a 2% cost of debt for banks. The careful reader nity c ost o f m oney. A d ollar t oday a nd a d ollar a y ear f rom n ow a re n ot T he t ime v alue o f m oney i s r elated t o t he o pportunity c ost o f m oney. A d ollar t oday a nd a d ollar a y ear f rom n ow a re n ot 013 was 4.74% (monthly spot rate). <http://www.treasury.gov/resource-‐ There rare many considerations a risk-free rate. Thebecause ofne nomic-‐policy/corp-‐bond-‐yield/Pages/Corp-‐Yield-‐Bond-‐Curve-‐Papers.aspx> the ro6 equired a rfisky is to lcess ompensate he or ctould he hat ould bbanks’ e Tehus, arned oof n their money. to be Ae darn ollar io an y ear rom naow ito s m westimating orth a dpollar arn interest on fact tche m oney. part of mayienterest note the todd that cost debt is assumed dollar today, because ne cequal. ould eturn nterest on tsset he oney. Tthan hus, art ttooday, f investor es/Corp-‐Yield-‐Bond-‐Curve-‐Papers.aspx> 5 standard methodology among finance toinvestor select the required return oan cny aost risky asset is to practitioners compensate tis he for the interest t hat c t rom ould b nvestor e e arned of or n tot heir m oney. f purchasing 8ear less that the assumption on the risk-free rate. This is related alue o f m oney i s r elated t o t he o pportunity o f m oney. A d ollar t oday a nd a d ollar a y f n ow a re n T he r equired r eturn o n r isky a sset m ust a lso i nclude c ompensation t o he i t he l oss o power toover 2 See: PWC (2013), King (2009) and Handorf (2011) e the investor the interest that could e oean arned oTreasury heir maoney. are portunity cost foor f m oney. Aeither 5d Tollar today abnd adny ollar an ytear fyield. rom ninclude ow not 8 10-year or 30-year U.S. One can also use 9 he raequired return risky a sset must lso compensation to the investor f.2*(7%) or t(2013), he banks l=oss of engage p((urchasing pandorf ower o(transformation ver S3he ee: King 2009) ain nd 2011) the that maturity (maturity of % fact +m P1WC T1hus, 1.5% including sHome rounding). lar a y ear f rom n ow i s w orth l ess t han a d ollar t oday, b ecause o ne c ould e arn i nterest o n t oney. p art o f the l ife o f t he i nvestment. 9 clude t o t he i nvestor f or t he l oss o f p urchasing p ower o ver 10 han a dcompensation ollar today, b ecause o ne c ould e arn i nterest o n t he m oney. T hus, p art o f the l ife o f t he i nvestment. historical averages. In general, the maturity of the risk-free rate 3 % + 1 .2*(7%) = 1 1.5% ( including s ome r ounding). E lliot ( 2013) u ses a 2 % c ost o f d ebt f or b anks. T he c areful r eader m ay n ote t he o dd f act t hat banks’ cost of debt is assumed to risk-freetheir rate matches asset life while borrowings are short-term in 6 compensate the investor for the interest that could be earned 10 on m d return tohe n ainvestor risky 6a Tsset o mssumption atshould re many o m risk-‐free ate. The smtandard mong inance phis ractitioners iay s fact tno iTnterest here are cm any onsiderations to eestimating stimating a ra isk-‐free rate. standard ethodology aethodology mong foney. inance p aoractitioners tro Ellliot 2013) a 2% cost of the debt ffor bis anks. careful reader ote the odd feact that in banks’ cost transformation of debt is assumed to be ess t(hat the uases n risk-‐free ate. TThe is related to tm he that banks ngage maturity match thecclife of the with the 30-year Treasury pensate fhere or tis he tonsiderations hat ould be investment, etarned on their oney. Trhe nature). select 1include r c3ompensation 0-‐year U.S. O ne O also use hlso istorical n gisk-‐free the mmatches aturity of the isk-‐ be that trhe assumption oIo n ver tg he ate. his is related to he fact that engage in maturity transformation ed return ny rselect isky asset mtust a0-‐year lso to ytield. he nvestor or tahe loss f verages. pless urchasing power (maturity oIf rate arisk-‐free sset life rtw hile Tm b orrowings aore in bnanks ature). emither ae 1ither or for 3o0-‐year U TTpreasury reasury yield. ne cfver an use oah istorical aeneral, verages. n eneral, he aturity f stthort-‐term he risk-‐ yield used toaassess perpetuity value. -‐free rate. oTn he standard ethodology a0-‐year mong fhe inance p.S. ractitioners iis tower o can also include caompensation tfree o he i nvestor t l oss o f urchasing p o 11 f nlever risk-‐free rate matches lbife wb hile borrowings short-‐term in nature). rate should match the life of the investment, with the 30-‐year Treasury yield (maturity u sed o aoussess erpetuity value. sset We ctan and relever the eaquity eta y the following afre he 11 rate 7should match life otf he the investment, with the 30-‐year T11 reasury yield upsed o assess p erpetuity alue. f ormulas: We can unlever relever theequity equity beta following d. Oinvestment. ne can also use free historical ahe verages. In at gfhe eneral, m aturity f the risk-‐ !"# !! o ,!!"# We can unlever aand nd rtelever the beta by tby he vfthe ollowing ormulas: T f ormula f or irm’s ( i) b eta i s: 𝛽𝛽 = T his e quation s ays t hat a f irm’s b eta i s v olatility o f t he f irm’s e quity, 7 The formula for a firm’s (i) beta is: This equation ! !"# ! ,! 7 to estimating a risk-‐free rate. The standard !"#$ !"# (!!"# many ethodology among sfays inance paractitioners is −tvo !"# formulas: 𝛽𝛽 𝛽𝛽!"#"$"%b /(1 + i1s 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡 )o f the firm’s equity, ith he considerations 30-‐year Treasury yield uthat sed o fairm’s ssess erpetuity vof alue. t o ! mt) he The formula fethodology or (i) bathe eta is: 𝛽𝛽a!nd = This t!"#$%$&$' hat =firm’s eta olatility g a rtisk-‐free rate. The standard m apismong finance p!"# (! ractitioners teo quation !"#$%& !"#$ says attafirm’s beta volatility the firm’s equity, correlated o the m arket s a w hole scaled verall is volatility of the market. ) 𝛽𝛽t!"#$%$&$' = 𝛽𝛽!"#"$"% /(1 +he 1 −risk-‐ 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡 ) !"#o r y ay 1ield. 0-‐year o r 3 0-‐year U .S. T reasury y ield. O ne c an a lso u se h istorical a verages. I n g eneral, he m aturity o f t !"#$%& One can says also tu se ah istorical ato verages. general, he maturity ooverall f tohe risk-‐volatility of the market. correlated the ao whole and too the This equation hat firm’s beta is vmarket olatility f the ftirm’s equity, !"#$ to the m arket as In aas hole aTnd sscaled caled the verall 𝛽𝛽!"#"$"% =v𝛽𝛽alue. ) ould w mith atch the life correlated of Ttreasury he investment, wmarket. ith 3 w0-‐year reasury ytield ∗ (1 + 1 − 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡 !"#$%& !"#$%$&$' 3 !"#$ volatility of the ent, the 30-‐year yield used to tahe ssess perpetuity value. used to assess perpetuity 𝛽𝛽!"#"$"% = 𝛽𝛽!"#$%$&$' ∗ (1 + 1 − 𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡𝑡 !"#$%& ) !"# ! ,! he o verall v olatility o f t he m arket. ! !"# !la ,! 12 T his e quation s ays t hat a f irm’s b eta i s v olatility o f t he f irm’s e quity, ! for !"#a firm’s (i) beta is: 𝛽𝛽! = A ssume a b ank e quity b eta o f 1 .2 a nd c ost o f e quity of 11.5%, a tax rate of 35%, This equation says that a firm’s beta is volatility of the firm’s equity, 3 and a starting capital structure of 94% (! ) !"# (!!"# ) 12 !"# o market as vaolatility w scaled to the hole aond d tthe o the overall f the market. overall volatility of the market. 3 3 Assume Tahe bank equity beta of 1.2 and c+ost of equity W of e 1c1.5%, a tax of 35%, and oaf s0tarting capital tructure of 94% leverage. WACC is 2.6% [(.0115*.06) (.02*.94)]. alculate an ruate nlevered beta .11 using the asbove formula (1.2 / (1 leverage. The WACC s 2.6% [(.0115*.06) (.02*.94)]. We calculate an unlevered beta f 0.11 using tw he ormula (1.2 / (1 + (.65) * (.06/.94)) = .i11. Relevering at a n+ew, more equity-‐reliant capital structure of 8o5% leverage, e agbove et a bfeta of .50, and a + (.65) * (.06/.94)) Relevering t aACC new, m.7% ore [e(.065*.15) quity-‐reliant capital structure 85% leverage, we tghe et incremental a beta of .50, and new cost of equity =o f .11. 6.5%. The new aW is 2 + (.02*.85)]. The .1% odf ifference reflects loss of a Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 new shields. cost of equity of 6.5%. The new WACC is 2.7% [(.065*.15) + (.02*.85)]. The .1% difference reflects the incremental loss of tax tax shields. 3 39 4 4 Too Much of a Good Thing: The Implications of Higher Capital Requirements equity (11.5%) than cheaper debt (2%), the cost of the equity will decline to precisely offset new capital structure weightings (see footnote for formulas and calculations).12 Of course, all things being equal, a less levered bank will be able to borrow more cheaply, too. growth, or financial stability (Admati and Hellwig 2013). The argument rests on a gross oversimplification of the complexities involved in bank capital structure. Empirical support for beta’s responsiveness to changes in leverage is pfar less established in reality thantit in real assets will hav assets to maximize cash flows. Rearranging the roportion of paper claims o isthese The idea that the cost of equity precisely theory & Amit 1999, Baker & Wugler 2013). no effect on cdeclines ost of ctoapital, asset value, or (Abuaf firm value. offset additional reliance on more expensive equity Corporate finance research that assesses the factors is conceptually sound subject to numerous involved in estimating of capitalcand capital The though MM irrelevance proposition is the starting point for cost analyzing apital structure; it is not the ending simplifying assumptions—assumptions that vary in the structure decisions often exclude banks altogether due and perfectly rationa point. Its conditions are crlaims igorous, including no taxes, no asymmetric information, assets to maximize cash flows. Rearranging the proportion of paper to these real assets will have degree whichothey reflect reality. Indeed, the foregoing world. to the nature banks’tuse leverage andyet theremains foundational no effect on cost of capital, asset tovalue, r risk-‐based firm value. p ricing—a frictionless Munique M does not of reflect he of real world, analysis took into because account only the narrow set of factors. role of regulation (King 2009). There are surprisingly it forces us to be precise about those factors that make capital structure decisions important. The MM irrelevance proposition is the starting point for analyzing capital structure; it istudies s not the nding few on ethe cost of bank equity and there is a clear reality, there asymmetric re a number of factors related to crational apital structure choice that do matter. But some use point. Its conditions are rigorous, i ncluding n o t axes, n o a i nformation, a nd p erfectly Discussions of capital structure and corporate finance need to examine further the trade-offs at stake with bank this theoretical, foundation to aoundational rgue that there is “no cost…whatsoever” to higher bank risk-‐based pricing—a frictionless world. M theoretical does not rframework eflect conceptual the rof eal world, yet remains often begin withMthe Modigliani capitalfstructure (Berlin 2011). equity capital in terms of loan ipmportant. ricing, credit because it forces us to be and precise about those factors tthat, hat requirements munder ake ccertain apital structure decisions In availability, economic growth, or financial Miller (MM), which shows stability (Admati and ellwig 2013). argument reality, there are a number of factors related tcash o capital structure cHhoice that do mThe atter. But some urests se on a gross oversimplification of the complexiti conditions and when flows are held constant, the this theoretical, conceptual f oundation t o a rgue t hat t here i s “ no c ost…whatsoever” t o h igher b ank involved carries in bank apital tructure. amount of debt a company has cno effectson its equity capital requirements in terms loan pricing, credit aThe vailability, economic growth, or financial of Bank Capital value. Capitalof structure is irrelevant. MM framework The Relevance Empirical s upport f or b eta’s r esponsiveness tco omplexities changes in leverage is far less established in reality than stability (Admati and Hellwig 2 013). The a rgument r ests o n a g ross o versimplification o f t he illustrates an important point: most companies create Structure involved in bank capital structure. is their in theory & Acash mit flows. 1999, Baker & Wugler 2013). Corporate finance research that assesses the value by managing assets to(Abuaf maximize factors involved in estimating cost of capital and apital structure ecisions Rearranging the proportion of paper claims to these real A number ofcreal-world frictions ddeviate fromoften the exclude banks Empirical support for beta’s responsiveness to changes in leverage is far less established in reality than it to the asset unique ature irrelevance of banks’ condition use of leverage a nd t he r ole o f regulation (King 2009). assets will have noaltogether effect on costdue of capital, value,nor of a Modigliani and Miller world. is in theory (Abuaf & Amit 1999, Baker & Wugler 2013). Corporate finance research that assesses the firm value. Inthe general, debt can impact the value cashnflows There re surprisingly ew studies on cost of bank equity and a coflear eed tfor o examine further the factors involved in estimating cost of capital and a capital structure dfecisions often exclude banks banks(Berlin and nonbanks in five primary ways: tax tradeoffs t stake w ith the bank capital sboth tructure altogether due to the unique nature of banks’ use of aleverage and role of regulation (King 2009). 2011). The MM irrelevance proposition is the starting point benefits, market signaling, flexibility, distress costs, and There are surprisingly few studies on the c ost of bank equity and a clear need to examine further the for analyzing capital structure; it is not the ending management incentives (Higgins 2011). In addition, a tradeoffs at stake with bank capital structure (Berlin 2011). point. Its conditions are rigorous, including no taxes, number The R elevance o f B ank C apital S tructure of factors unique to banks impact their cost of no asymmetric information, and perfectly rational capital, including socially valuable liquidity production; of rworld. eal-‐world frictions from tand he iregulatory rrelevance condition f aeffect Modigliani and Miller worl The Relevance of Bank Capital Structure A number risk-based pricing—a frictionless MM does not deviate competitive dynamics; and o the of reflect the real world, yet remains foundational because programs In general, debt can impact the value government of cash flows for blike oth deposit banks insurance. and nonbanks in five primary ways: A number of real-‐world frictions deviate from the irrelevance condition of a Modigliani and Miller world. it forces us to be precise about those factorssthat make flexibility, distress costs, and management incentives (Higgins 2011). In tax benefits, market ignaling, In general, debt can impact the value of cash flows for both banks and nonbanks in five primary ways: capital structure decisions important. In reality, there unique to Taxes addition, a number of factors banks impact their cost of capital, including socially valuable tax benefits, market signaling, flexibility, distress costs, and management incentives (Higgins 2011). In are a number of factors related to capital structure liquidity production; and rsegulatory dynamics; and the effect of government programs like addition, a number of factors unique to banks impact their cost ocf ompetitive capital, including ocially valuable choice that do matter. But some use this theoretical, The most common jumping off point from a MM deposit insurance. liquidity production; competitive and regulatory dynamics; and the effect of government programs like conceptual foundation to argue that there is “no cost… perspective on capital structure is the effect of taxes. In deposit insurance. whatsoever” to higher bank equity capital requirements the U.S., as in many developed countries, interest costs Taxes in terms of loan pricing, credit availability, economic are a deductible expense for tax purposes. The effect of Taxes in M capital structure is tooreduce taxesstructure and create is the effect of taxes The most common jumping off point leverage from an M perspective n capital The most common jumping off point from In an the MM p erspective o n c apital s tructure i s t he e ffect o f t axes. an “interest tax shield. ” These are incremental cash flows s icost n mofany eveloped 12 Assume a bank equity betaUof.S., 1.2 a and equitydof 11.5%, a countries, interest costs are a deductible expense for tax purposes. In the U.S., as in many developed c ountries, i nterest c osts a re a d eductible e xpense f or t ax p urposes. that firms generate from theirand usecofreate leverage. interesttax shield.” These tax rate of 35%, and a starting capital structure of 94% The effect of leverage in cleverage. apital structure is to reduce taxes an “The interest ThesWACC is 2.6%is [(.0115*.06) (.02*.94)]. calculate The effect of leverage in capital tructure to reduce +taxes and We create an an “interest tax tax shield shield.” hese in valuation that it’s integrated is soTprevalent ncremental cash (1.2 flows unlevered beta ofare 0.11iusing the above formula / (1 +that (.65) firms generate from their use of leverage. The interest tax shield is so are incremental cash flows that firms generate from their use of leverage. The interest tax into shield s so portion of the WACC formula: directly the idebt * (.06/.94)) = .11. Relevering at a new, more equity-reliant capital ! ! prevalent i n v aluation t hat i t’s d irectly i nto t he d ebt pThis ortion of tsays he W ACC freal ormula: 𝐾𝐾! (1 − 𝑡𝑡)( ). Th structure of 85% leverage, we get a beta of .50, and a new cost of prevalent in valuation that it’s directly into the debt portion of the WACC formula: 𝐾𝐾! (1 − 𝑡𝑡)( ). . This formula that the cost !!! !!! equity of 6.5%. The new WACC is 2.7% [(.065*.15) + (.02*.85)]. Thus, a firm introduces more ays that the eal cTost s introduces an isaan fter-‐tax cost of idebt after-tax cost ((𝐾𝐾! (1 − 𝑡𝑡)). ). Thus, asaas firm (1 −rtax 𝑡𝑡)). hus, oaf s daebt firm more formula says that the real cost of .1% debt is aformula n reflects after-‐tax cost (𝐾𝐾!loss The difference thesincremental of shields. leverage into biecause ts capital structure, WACC goes down, leverage into its capital structure, its WACC goes down, debt is cheaper its than equity even on a because debt is cheaper than equity even on a risk-‐adjusted basis. That is, an increased erisk-‐adjusted quity beta from n increase in aleverage will no longer bpeta erfectly baasis. That is, n increased equity from an increase in leverage will no longer perfect Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 offset f capital, nd chost ence rate it Ac harges loans, ill go uap nd hence the rate it charges on loans, will go up 40in the cost of capital. A bank’s cost ooffset in tahe of the capital. bank’s ocn ost of cwapital, the more the bank is required to rely on equity. T his e ffect o n b anks’ c ost o f c apital h as b een quantified the more the bank is required to rely on equity. This effect on banks’ cost of capital has been quantifie It becomes clear Your current situation. The path forward. Your real options. Your needs and responsibilities. When you have quality, integrity and trust as the foundation for doing business, the issues become clear and often so do the answers. Through our global network of firms with more than 180,000 people in 157 countries, we provide quality advisory, assurance and tax services to many of the world’s most successful companies. For more information on how we can help you address your business challenges, visit us at pwc.com, pwcregulatory.com or contact: Dan Ryan Financial Services Advisory Leader [email protected] (646) 471 8488 © 2013 PwC. All rights reserved. PwC refers to the PwC network and/or one or more of its member firms, each of which is a separate legal entity. Please see www.pwc.com/structure for further details. This content is for general information purposes only, and should not be used as a substitute for consultation with professional advisors. Too Much of a Good Thing: The Implications of Higher Capital Requirements introduces more leverage into its capital structure, its WACC goes down, because debt is cheaper than equity even on a risk-adjusted basis. That is, an increased equity beta from an increase in leverage will no longer precisely offset in the cost of capital. A bank’s cost of capital, and hence the rate it charges on loans, will go up the more the bank is required to rely on equity. This effect on banks’ cost of capital has been quantified by a number of authors (Elliot 2009; Stein and Hanson 2010), each of which predict a moderate increase in lending rates. ‘‘ Calibrating capital requirements only with respect to bank failure is problematic in that it does not account for bank lending functions and ignores the trade-off between a lower probability of bank failure and continuation of lending. Asymmetric Information, Management Incentives and Growth Another important way that capital structure can impact bank lending is through the incentives that leverage provides to management in the context of asymmetric information regarding a bank’s assets and growth opportunities. A benefit of leverage is that in certain circumstances it can increase alignment between the interests of shareholders and management. The addition of fixed interest expenses to a business’s operating profile can help discipline management to deploy the firm’s cash flows to valuable projects (Higgins 2011). The manner in which debt can align shareholder and management incentives varies by the investment opportunities a firm confronts. McConnell and Servaes (1995) empirically demonstrate that for “low growth” 42 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 firms in mature industries, “value is positively correlated with leverage” (page 123). In their analysis, leverage helps to equilibrate between “overinvestment and underinvestment” problems. The set of investment opportunities combined with the interplay of shareholdermanagement incentives will create an optimal amount of leverage for firms. Given the well-documented asymmetric information problems unique to banks’ assets and the mature, highly developed nature of bank industry conditions, it’s likely that this effect is present and would impact banks’ lending decisions. McConnell and Servaes conclude that empirical, real world data show that “debt policy and equity ownership structure ‘matter.’” Deposits and Liquidity Production In the banking literature, banks are often described as “special,” and their specialness derives in part from the fact that they create liquid deposits that serve as money in our economy. But deposits are a funding source for banks, a form of bank debt, and banks are thus unique from most other companies in that they produce socially valuable services from the debt liabilities in their capital structure. Recall that nonbanks create value only from their assets. Because consumers and businesses demand a liquid, ready source of funds, there will be a pricing signal, or a premium, to provide liquid claims in the form of deposits (De Angelo and Stulz 2013). In providing deposits, banks create value directly through their capital structure choices, and debt and equity are not precisely equivalent risk-adjusted sources of capital for banks. This is a clear departure from a theoretical MM world. DeAngelo and Stulz (2013) show that the provision of “(privately and socially beneficial) liquid financial claims” makes high leverage optimal for banks before taking into account taxes, asymmetric information, deposit insurance, or any other real-world frictions. They further argue that because MM does not contemplate the provision of deposit liabilities, MM “is an inappropriately equity-biased baseline for assessing” bank capital structure choices (page 3). Returning to WACC, it follows that singling out banks for substantially heightened equity capital requirements Our comprehensive service will help you piece together the complex regulatory requirements of the US, UK, EU and beyond ABU DHABI | BEIJING | BRUSSELS | FRANKFURT | HONG KONG | LONDON | MILAN | NEW YORK | PALO ALTO PARIS | ROME | SAN FRANCISCO | SÃO PAULO | SHANGHAI | SINGAPORE | TOKYO | TORONTO | WASHINGTON, DC shearman.com Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 43 Too Much of a Good Thing: The Implications of Higher Capital Requirements will increase banks’ overall cost of capital and thus loan rates. This is due to a premium associated with bank deposits as a financing source and, compared with equity capital, bank deposits are a less expensive source of debt capital (even on a risk-adjusted basis). Moreover, bank deposits benefit from FDIC insurance, and while banks pay premiums for this insurance, the presence of official support will dampen the risk sensitivity of the providers of this funding source and reduce the cost of deposit funding compared to equity.13 ‘‘ If asset shrinkage—perhaps by cutting back on lending—is limited to a single bank, then other banks can potentially pick up the slack without major implications for intermediation activity. However, there are serious consequences if multiple banks respond to higher capital requirements by reducing the flow of credit to the economy. Equity Capital, Intermediation, and Financial Stability The discussion thus far suggests that equity capital is more expensive relative to debt for banks. But what are the implications of requiring banks to have more capital in their funding mix? Would the heightened capital requirements have any implications for intermediation activity? If so, are there further implications for investment on the part of the borrowers? Would they seek credit elsewhere and what does it mean for financial stability? 13 Indeed, many argue that this is the reason that high leverage is optimal for banks. 44 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Most discussions of bank capital regulation start from the premise that the goal is to keep the probability of bank failure below a certain fixed threshold, typically set in terms of a “confidence level.” A confidence level of 99.9%, for example, means that there is only a 0.1% chance that potential losses will exceed the sum of “expected” and “unexpected” losses, thus ensuring that probability of bank failure remains low. Once the confidence level is set, the necessary level of capital can be calibrated using information in each bank’s portfolio (Gordy, 2003). Calibrating capital requirements only with respect to bank failure is problematic in that it does not account for bank lending functions and ignores the trade-off between a lower probability of bank failure and continuation of lending. In some states of the world, improvements in financial stability may outweigh the costs of lower output growth, thus justifying higher capital requirements. In other circumstances, however, improvements in financial stability may only be marginal relative to foregone lending opportunities, thus making capital requirements “inefficiently” high. Changes in capital requirements may affect lending in two ways. First, as we have shown in the previous sections, raising bank capital requirements results in higher WACC (Baker and Wurgler, 2013). Thus, if a bank’s cost of capital exceeds the rate of return derived from cash flows from a new loan, the loan will not be made or the bank will increase the rate charged for the loan to cover its cost of capital. Too-stringent capital requirements may result in reduction in the supply of credit, underinvestment in the economy, and thus slower economic growth. Alternatively, note that capital requirements are stated in terms of ratios. Faced with increasing capital requirements relative to total assets or risk-weighted assets, banks may respond by shrinking their size. To be specific, consider a bank with assets of $100 that is financed with deposits and $6 of equity capital, thus having 6% of equity capital relative to assets. Suppose that a new policy requires the capital ratio to be at least 10% relative to total assets. The bank can fulfill the new requirement by either raising $4 of fresh equity or by leaving its current level of equity unchanged and shrinking its assets to $60. A CRITICAL BALANCE For every well-run company, striking the right balance between risk and reward is always critical. Today, unprecedented regulatory changes and obligations make doing so more challenging than ever. Promontory can help you achieve and maintain the right balance. promontory.com | t +1 202 384 1200 WASHINGTON, D.C. • ATLANTA • BEIJING • BRUSSELS • DENVER • DUBAI • DUBLIN • HONG KONG • LONDON MADRID • MILAN • NEW YORK • PARIS • SAN FRANCISCO • SINGAPORE • SYDNEY • TOKYO • TORONTO If asset shrinkage—perhaps by cutting back on lending—is limited to a single bank, then other banks can potentially pick up the slack without major implications for intermediation activity. However, there are serious consequences if multiple banks respond to higher capital requirements by reducing the flow of credit to the economy. Moreover, asset shrinkage on the part of the regulated banks may push borrowers to seek credit in a less regulated environment, with potentially negative consequences for financial stability. Equity Capital and Intermediation There is a large literature that explores how shocks to bank capital impact lending and economic activity. One of the cleanest studies in this area is by Joe Peek and Eric Rosengren (1997). Their key insight is that the sharp decline in Japanese stock prices between 1989 and 1992 was transmitted to the United States via U.S. branches of Japanese parent banks. Specifically, they find that a one percentage point decline in the Japanese parent’s risk-based capital ratio resulted in a 6% decline in loans originated by the U.S. branches. In a subsequent study, Peek and Rosengren (2000) analyze the implications of the decline in lending for real economic activity. They find that the decline in lending was followed by a sharp reduction in commercial real estate activity in the U.S., especially in states with more U.S. branches of Japanese parent banks. Haubrich and Wachtel (1993) analyze the response of U.S. commercial banks to the 1988-89 announcement and implementation of higher capital requirements. They group the banks by their undercapitalization relative to the new minimum capital requirements and further segment the banks by their size. Haubrich and Wachtel find that relatively undercapitalized banks of all sizes shifted the composition of their portfolio in response to the new capital requirements, effectively shrinking their risk-weighted assets. The results are consistent with Bernanke and Lown (1991), who find a similar pattern of asset shrinkage in response to capital depletion among banks in New Jersey during the late 1980s. 46 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 In a more recent study, Francis and Osborne (2009) analyze the lending implications of bank-specific, timevarying capital requirements set by regulatory authorities in the U.K. They carefully construct a time series of bankspecific capital shortfalls and surpluses for the period 1996-2007 and estimate whether banks with capital shortfalls adjust their lending behavior. Their regression analyses suggest that a one percentage point increase in capital ratio results in a 2.4% reduction in risk-weighted assets, a 1.4% reduction in total assets, and a 1.2% reduction in lending over a period of four years. Equity Capital and Financial Stability Further, the implications of higher capital requirements for financial stability are not clear-cut. On the one hand, higher capital requirements reduce probability of default by forcing shareholders to absorb a larger fraction of losses in times of distress and by mitigating moral hazard concerns associated with excessive risk taking. On the other hand, faced with heightened capital requirements, banks can respond by selling illiquid assets causing asset prices to decline. Similar assets held by other market participants may decline in value as well, causing additional asset sell off. This self-reinforcing process increases system-wide financial fragility. Elements of this mechanism have been described in Shleifer and Vishny (1992). Furthermore, increasing evidence shows that regulatory burden and capital requirements steer some of the traditional banking activities towards the shadow banking sector. With less supervisory oversight and more uncertainty about the quality of lending, the growth of shadow banks poses concerns about allocation of credit, output growth, and financial stability. Aiyar, Calomiris, and Wieladek (2014) use a clever design to assess the impact of changes in capital requirements on bank lending and the allocation of credit. Specifically, the authors use differences in minimum capital requirements for U.K. banks between 1998 and 2007 and find that a 100 basis point increase in minimum capital requirement for banks regulated by the Financial Services Authority leads to 6-9% reduction in lending. Further, their analysis suggests that about one-third of the reduction in lending is picked up by branches of foreign-owned banks not regulated by the FSA. Although foreign-owned banks pick up some of the lending slack and offset the overall impact on lending, the “leakage” of lending to less-regulated areas of the banking system poses concerns for financial stability. The present debate about the efficient level of bank equity focuses on the implications of additional capital requirements for financial stability and economic growth. At the core of the debate is the cost of equity relative to debt and how the equity-debt cost differential changes when banks are required to alter their funding mix. On the one hand, theory suggests that capital structure has no impact on the cost of equity relative to debt (Modigliani and Miller, 1958) suggesting that there is no reason banks should not face significantly higher minimum capital requirements (Admati et al, 2013). However, when abstracting from the stylized and plainly unrealistic conditions in Modigliani and Miller with, for example, the introduction of taxes, asymmetric information, and deposit funding, then the equity-debt mix becomes important in determining the relative price of equity. Regulators are probably aware that capital is more expensive than debt and too-stringent capital requirements may dampen intermediation activities. Otherwise, why not set requirements significantly higher? Indeed, existing empirical literature suggests that heightened capital requirements are often met with a reduction in lending, with implications for investment activity and migration of lending to less regulated environments. It is important that policymakers evaluate the substantial regulatory policies imposed on the banking industry thus far and carefully consider the macroeconomic implications of further increases in capital requirements. References 2010. Admati, Anat, Peter M. DeMarzo, Martin F. Hellwig, and Paul Pfleiderer (2013), “Fallacies, Irrelevant Facts, and Myths in the Discussion of Capital Regulation: Why Bank Equity is Not Socially Expensive,” Rock Center for Corporate Governance Working Paper Series No. 161. DeAngelo, Harry and Rene M. Stulz, “Why High Leverage is Optimal for Banks,” May 2013. Aiyar, Shekhar, Charles W. Calomiris, and Tomasz Wieladek, “Does Macro-Prudential Regulation Leak? Evidence from a UK Policy Experiment,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 2014, Vol. 46, pp. 181-214. Francis, William and Matthew Osborne, “Bank Regulation, Capital and Credit Supply: Measuring the Impact of Prudential Standards,” FSA Occasional Paper Series No. 36, 2009. Angelini, Paolo, Laurent Clerc, Vasco Curdia, Leonardo Gambacorta, Andrea Gerali, Alberto Locarno, Roberto Motto, Werner Roeger, Skander Van den Heuvel, and Jan Vlcek, “BASEL III: Long-Term Impact on Economic Performance and Fluctuations,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 485, 2011. Handorf, William C., “Capital Management and Bank Value,” Journal of Banking Regulation, 2011, Vol. 12 (4), pp. 331-341. Peek, Joe and Eric Rosengren. “The International Transmission of Financial Shocks: The Case of Japan,” American Economic Review, 1997, Vol. 87(4), pp. 495505. Hanson, Samuel G., Anil K Kashyap, and Jeremy Stein, “A Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2011, Vol. 25(1), pp. 3-28. Peek, Joe and Eric Rosengren. “Collateral Damage: Effects of the Japanese Bank Crisis on Real Activity in the United States,” American Economic Review, 2000, Vol. 90(1), pp. 30-45. Higgins, Robert, Analysis for Financial Management, 10th ed. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill, 2012. Posner, Eric, “How Do Bank Regulators Determine Capital Adequacy Requirements?” Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics, Working Paper No. 698, 2014. Baker, Malcolm and Jeffrey Wurgler, “Do Strict Capital Requirements Raise the Cost of Capital? Bank Regulation and the Low Risk Anomaly,” NBER Working Paper No. 19018, May 2013. Berlin, Mitchell, “Can We Explain Banks’ Capital Structures?” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review, Q2 2011. Bernanke, Ben S., and Cara S. Lown, “The Credit Crunch,” Brookings Paper on Economic Activity, Vol. 2, pp. 205-248. Carlson, Mark, Hui Shan, and Missaka Warusawitharana, “Capital Ratios and Bank Lending: A Matched Bank Approach,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 2013, Vol. 22(4), pp. 663-687. Elliott, Douglas, “Quantifying the Effects on Lending of Increased Capital Requirements,” Brookings Institution, September 2009. Hirtle, Beverly, Til Schuermann, and Kevin Stiroh, “Macroprudential Supervision of Financial Institutions: Lessons from the SCAP,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff Report No. 409, 2009. McConnell, John J. and Henri Servaes, “Equity Ownership and the Two Faces of Debt,” Journal of Financial Economics, 1995, Vol. 39, pp. 131-157. Modigliani, Franco and Merton H. Miller , “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment,” American Economic Review, 1958, Vol. 88, pp. 587-597. PricewaterhouseCoopers, “Banking Industry Reform: A New Equilibrium, Part 2: Detailed Report,” June 2013. Gordy, Michael B. “A Risk-Factor Model Foundation for Ratings-Based Bank Capital Rules,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 2003, Vol. 12, pp. 199-232. Rosengren, Eric, “Defining Financial Stability, and Some Policy Implications of Applying the Definition,” Keynote Remarks at the Stanford Finance Forum Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, June 2011. Kashyap, Anil K., Jeremy C. Stein and Samuel Hanson, “An Analysis of the Impact of “Substantially Heightened” Capital Requirements on Large Financial Institutions,” May Shleifer, Andrei and Robert W. Vishny, “Liquidation Values and Debt Capacity: A Market Equilibrium Approach,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 47(4), pp. 1343-1366. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 47 TCH αnalytics 1. The largest Bank Holding Companies are rapidly building up high quality capital… BHCs with assets above $100Bill. Smaller BHCs 14% 12% 10% 8% 2010-Q1 2011-Q1 2012-Q1 2013-Q1 2014-Q1 Chart 1 shows the evolution of the Common equity Tier 1 (CET1) risk-based ratio for Bank Holding Companies (BHC) with assets above $100Bill and for Bank Holding Companies with assets between $5Bill and $100Bill. On average, the largest Bank Holding Companies increase their CET1 risk-based ratio from 8.6% in the beginning of 2010 to 12.2% by 2014, representing a capital growth rate of more than 40%. Smaller BHCs, on the other hand, accumulate capital at a slower rate, with the CET1 risk-based ratio increasing from 10.5% to 12.1% between 2010-Q1 and 2014-Q1. The relatively rapid capital accumulation for the largest Bank Holding Companies reflects, in part, heightened capital requirements and compliance with the annual supervisory stress tests. Source: FR Y-9C. 2. …reducing their systemic risk… 48 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 BHCs with assets above $100Bill. (Left Scale) Smaller companies (Right Scale) 6% 0.8% Contribution to Systemic Risk Chart 2 shows the contribution of the largest Bank Holding Companies and their smaller counterparts to systemic risk. The contribution to systemic risk is based on the SRISK metric described in Viral Acharya, Robert Engle, and Matthew Richardson’s “Capital Shortfall: A New Approach to Ranking and Regulating Systemic Risk,” American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2012, 102(3), pp. 59-64. SRISK is a share of each firm’s capital shortfall relative to the overall capital shortfall in a hypothetical future crisis. The lines in the chart show the trend in average SRISK for the largest Bank Holding Companies – those with assets above $100Bill – and for smaller financial companies with market capitalization above $5Bill, as of 2007-Q2. The chart shows a clear downward trend in systemic risk for the largest Bank Holding Companies, with their share in overall capital shortfall steadily declining post 2012. The reduction in systemic risk is at least partly explained by their rapid capital accumulation. 5% 4% 3% 0.6% 0.4% 0.2% 2010-Q1 2011-Q1 2012-Q1 2013-Q1 Source: The Volatility Institute, <http://vlab.stern.nyu.edu/>. 2014-Q1 3. …and are growing slower than their smaller counterparts… Chart 3 shows asset growth for Bank Holding Companies with assets above $100Bill and for Bank Holding Companies with assets between $5Bill and $100Bill. For ease of comparison, assets are normalized to 100 at the beginning of the period (2010Q1). Between 2010-Q1 and 2014-Q1, assets of the largest BHCs grew by 8%, while assets of smaller Bank Holding Companies grew by 19%. The relatively slow asset growth of the largest BHCs, combined with their rapid capital accumulation (Chart 1) and reduction in systemic risk (Chart 2), points to the trade-off between financial stability and asset growth. BHCs with assets above $100Bill. Smaller BHCs 120 115 110 105 100 2010-Q1 2011-Q1 2012-Q1 2013-Q1 2014-Q1 Source: FR Y-9C. 4. …reflecting the trade-off between capital accumulation and asset growth. Chart 4 shows the correlation between capital accumulation and asset growth between 2010Q1 and 2014-Q1 for Bank Holding Companies with assets above $100Bill. Each circle represents a different Bank Holding Company. The size of each circle is proportional to assets size, with larger circles representing larger Bank Holding Companies. The dashed line marks the negative relationship between capital growth and asset growth (the correlation is statistically significant), quantifying the trade-off between capital accumulation and asset growth. 80% 60% 40% 20% 0 -20% 0 Source: FR Y-9C. 2ppt 4ppt 6ppt 8ppt Change in CET1 Risk-Based Ratio (2010Q1-2014Q1) Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 49 I It has been some time since we were last governed by a Republican-controlled Congress and a Democratic president. The last time was nearly fifteen years ago during the final six years of the Clinton Administration. Almost no one expects the next two years to yield the same legislative results as did that previous experiment in divided government. In fact, for a variety of reasons, not the least of which is the looming 2016 presidential election, it seems rather unlikely that the incoming 114th Congress will be as productive as any of those previous Congresses, measured in terms of enacted legislative output. Indeed, conventional wisdom (both inside and outside the Beltway, it would seem) holds that the next two years portend an extended and bitterly partisan political stalemate that will stymie any prospect for enactment of financial services legislation. Call me a contrarian, but I take a different view. Despite the partisan politics that will inevitably animate both ends of Pennsylvania Avenue over the next two years, there will be opportunities in the new Congress to enact meaningful (albeit targeted and incremental) financial services legislation. There are several potential procedural paths to enactment of such legislation. For example, there has been a lot of chatter in Washington recently about Congressional Republicans using the “budget reconciliation” process to circumvent Democratic-led filibusters in the Senate. There is also talk of attaching GOP legislative riders to appropriations bills and other “must-pass” legislation. But with Senate Republicans still short of a filibuster-proof majority and a Democratic president armed with a veto pen, the most likely avenue for enactment of financial services-related legislation in the new Congress will involve regular procedural order and bipartisan compromise. As discussed below, there 50 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 are already a few legislative proposals percolating on Capitol Hill around which a bipartisan consensus seems to be emerging. The new Congress is also likely to feature vigorous – and now bicameral – Congressional oversight of the Obama Administration and the financial regulatory agencies, which could be particularly impactful with respect to the ongoing regulatory implementation of the Dodd-Frank Act. Even if this optimistic outlook on the prospects for legislative action turns out to be Pollyannaish, the results of this month’s mid-term elections are certain to alter the balance of power with respect to executive branch nominations. Each of these topics is discussed in more detail below, with a focus on the possible legislative and oversight agendas of the key Congressional committees that exercise jurisdiction over the financial services industry. The Art of the Possible Prospects for Financial Services Legislation in the 114th Congress by Samuel Woodall III, Partner, Sullivan & Cromwell LLP Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 51 The Art of the Possible: Prospects for Financial Services Legislation in the 114th Congress Post-Election Landscape on Capitol Hill The new GOP majority in the Senate and the newlybuttressed Republican majority in the House are now poised to pursue a single legislative agenda, one that will likely focus on “big ticket” issues like energy policy and perhaps corporate tax reform. But Congressional Republicans will also have the opportunity to do something that has been off-limits for the last several years: amend Dodd-Frank. ‘‘ Despite the partisan politics that will inevitably animate both ends of Pennsylvania Avenue over the next two years, there will be opportunities in the new Congress to enact meaningful financial services legislation. 52 Frank.1 The House of Representatives subsequently approved a companion bill by a bipartisan majority.2 With near unanimous support in both chambers, coupled with recent testimony by Federal Reserve Board Governor Dan Tarullo, who said enactment of this legislation “would be very welcome,”3 it appears likely to be fast-tracked and reach President Obama’s desk during the “lame duck” session of the current Congress. Although admittedly technical in nature and targeted in scope, enactment of this legislation could presage a willingness on the part of Senate Democrats to entertain other, targeted amendments to Dodd-Frank in the new Congress. Senate Banking Committee Senator Richard Shelby (R-AL), who previously led the Banking Committee from 2003 to 2007, is poised to reassume the committee gavel for the remaining two years he is permitted to serve under the term limits imposed by Senate GOP rules. Under his leadership, the Committee will pursue a different set of legislative and oversight priorities than it did under the stewardship of outgoing Chairman Tim Johnson (D-SD), who has consistently supported the Obama Administration’s financial reform efforts and generally opposed amendments to Dodd-Frank (with the exception of the Collins Amendment legislation mentioned above). Since the enactment of the Dodd-Frank Act in 2010, the Obama Administration and its Democratic allies in the Senate have consistently and vigorously opposed legislation that would amend the Act. So resolute have Democrats been in defense of this position that some have described it as the political equivalent of the “11th Commandment: Thou Shalt Not Amend Dodd-Frank.” Like his predecessor, Chairman Shelby’s agenda will include Dodd-Frank oversight, but led this time by a staunch opponent of that legislation, which he strongly More recently, however, Senate Democrats, together with all of their Republican colleagues, did vote to amend Dodd-Frank. That unanimous, bipartisan vote occurred on a bill relating to the treatment of certain insurance companies under the “Collins Amendment” to Dodd- 1 S. 2270 (the “Insurance Capital Standards Clarification Act of 2014”), available at https://www.congress.gov/113/bills/s2270/ BILLS-113s2270es.pdf. 2 H.R. 5461, available at https://www.congress.gov/113/bills/ hr5461/BILLS-113hr5461rfs.pdf. 3 Daniel K. Tarullo, Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Dodd-Frank Implementation, Testimony before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, Washington, D.C. (Sept. 9, 2014), available at http:// federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/tarullo20140909a.htm. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 denounced in the Banking Committee4 and against which he voted on final passage. Indeed, Senator Shelby has repeatedly expressed concerns with Dodd-Frank-mandated regulations that he considers to be imprudent or unduly burdensome, including the Volcker Rule.5 Nor is it likely that he will hesitate to criticize the Obama Administration and the financial regulators – in particular the Federal Reserve, of which he has been a frequent and outspoken critic.6 ‘‘ Senator Shelby has also been a strong proponent of requiring regulators to conduct cost-benefit analyses of new regulations. In 2011, he introduced legislation,7 cosponsored by several Banking Committee Republicans, that would require regulators to conduct a “qualitative and quantitative assessment of all anticipated direct and indirect costs and benefits” of any proposed regulation, including compliance costs, effects on “job creation,” “regulatory administrative costs,” and any costs the regulation might impose on state and local governments. This emphasis on cost-benefit analysis is likely to be a signature aspect of his agenda as chairman. 4 Statement of Senator Richard Shelby, Senate Banking Committee, Executive Session to Mark-up an Original Bill Entitled “Restoring American Financial Stability Act of 2010” (March 22, 2010), available at http://www.banking.senate.gov/public/index. cfm?FuseAction=Files.View&FileStore_id=96cabd7f-a4df-4e02be38-e14d25c4c59f. 5 Hearing before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, 111th Congress – 2nd Session, Examining Recent Restrictions placed on Commercial Banks and Bank Holding Companies’ High-Risk Investment Activities (Feb. 2, 2010), available at http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/CHRG111shrg57709/html/CHRG-111shrg57709.htm. See Statement of Senator Richard Shelby: “…there does not seem to be evidence that . . . that proprietary trading created the losses that resulted in the rate need and race for bailouts.” 6 Brandon Moseley, Shelby Says that Federal Reserve has Engaged in “A Backdoor Stimulus Program through Monetary Policy,” Alabama Political Reporter (Jan. 9, 2014), available at http:// alreporter.com/archives/2012-september/146-state/5581shelby-says-that-federal-reserve-has-engaged-in-a-backdoorstimulus-program-through-monetary-policy.html. “I have long been concerned that this aggressive and extraordinary purchasing program is artificially propping up home prices. This is especially pertinent since an over-heated housing market greatly contributed to the financial crisis that caused this situation in the first place.” 7 Like his predecessor, Senator Shelby has consistently expressed concerns with the regulatory burden imposed on community banks and may, as he has in the past,8 seek to advance a package of “regulatory relief ” measures intended primarily to benefit smaller banking organizations. At times, however, he has also been a harsh critic of the largest banks, perhaps most notably during the Dodd-Frank legislative debate when he voted for the Volcker Rule and cast one of only three Republican votes in favor of an amendment offered by Senators Kaufman (D-DE) and Brown (D-OH) that would have effectively broken up the largest banking S.1615 (the “Financial Regulatory Responsibility Act of 2011”), available at https://www.congress.gov/112/bills/s1615/BILLS112s1615is.pdf. Congressional Republicans will also have the opportunity to do something that has been off-limits for the last several years: amend Dodd-Frank. organizations in the United States.9 Moreover, in 1999, he voted against the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, the legislation that partially repealed the Glass-Steagall Act’s separation of commercial and investment banking. He has also suggested, on more than one occasion, that capital standards should be higher for the largest banks.10 8 Id. 9 U.S. Senate Roll Call Vote #136, 111th Congress – 2nd Session (May 6, 2010), available at http://www.senate. gov/legislative/LIS/roll_call_lists/roll_call_vote_cfm. cfm?congress=111&session=2&vote=00136. The amendment failed by a vote count of 33 to 61. 10 Hearing before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, 112th Congress – 2nd Session, Implementing Wall Street Reform: Enhancing Bank Supervision And Reducing Systemic Risk (June 6, 2012), available at http://www.gpo.gov/ fdsys/pkg/CHRG-112shrg78813/pdf/CHRG-112shrg78813.pdf. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 53 The Art of the Possible: Prospects for Financial Services Legislation in the 114th Congress One issue on which Senators Shelby and Johnson strongly disagree is housing finance reform. Describing the issue as the Committee’s “top priority,”11 Chairman Johnson and Ranking Minority Member Mike Crapo (R-ID) brokered an agreement earlier this year with a bill that would have eliminated Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and established a new housing finance regulator and backstop guarantor.12 Although approved by the committee with some Republican support, Senator Shelby voted against the measure, arguing that it would “complicate an already complex problem by expanding the role of the federal government in our private housing finance market and creating, yet again, another massive regulator.”13 In this regard, Senator Shelby’s position on the issue of housing finance reform is more aligned with that of current House Financial Services Committee Chairman Jeb Hensarling (R-TX).14 Given the continued divisiveness of this issue in Congress, the ongoing recovery of the housing markets in the U.S., and the very limited window of opportunity to develop, debate, and pass major legislation in advance of the 2016 presidential and Congressional elections, passage of comprehensive housing finance reform legislation does not appear to be in the cards in the 114th Congress. Even if Senate Republicans maintain their majority after the 2016 elections, as noted above, Senator Shelby can only serve as chairman of the Banking Committee for two more years, which leaves precious little time to see new legislation through to enactment, especially against 11 Senate Banking Committee, Johnson, Crapo Continue Work on Housing Finance Reform (Feb. 5, 2014), available at http://www. banking.senate.gov/public/index.cfm?FuseAction=Newsroom. PressReleases&ContentRecord_id=27117999-d992-2666-eb7316d9b210a581. 12 Senate Banking Committee, Johnson, Crapo Continue Work on Housing Finance Reform (Feb. 5, 2014), available at http://www. banking.senate.gov/public/index.cfm?FuseAction=Newsroom. PressReleases&ContentRecord_id=27117999-d992-2666-eb7316d9b210a581. 54 the backdrop of divided government. Accordingly, Chairman Shelby will likely be inclined to prioritize regulatory burden relief for smaller banks, although as discussed below, such legislation could potentially include some targeted relief for the larger banks. House Financial Services Committee With Republicans still in firm control of the House of Representatives and leadership of the House Financial Services Committee expected to remain largely intact, the financial services agenda on the House side of the Capitol is likely to resemble in many respects the agenda Chairman Hensarling has pursued in his committee over the last two years. In stark contrast to the Senate, the House has passed literally dozens of bills over the last four years that would amend Dodd-Frank, with the Financial Services Committee approving more than 30 such bills in the 113th Congress alone, none of which has advanced in the Senate. Obviously, it should be easier for Chairman Hensarling to get the Senate Banking Committee’s attention beginning next year. The Financial Services Committee has also conducted numerous Dodd-Frank oversight hearings in the 113th Congress, during which the panel’s Republican members have been harshly critical of the Obama Administration, the federal banking agencies, and the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC), scrutiny that will only intensify now that the GOP is the majority party on both sides of the Capitol. The harshest of this bicameral scrutiny is likely to be reserved for the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB), an agency Senator Shelby has described as the “most powerful yet unaccountable bureaucracy in the federal government”15 and Chairman Hensarling has characterized as the “single most unaccountable agency in the history of America.”16 Accordingly, Congressional Republicans will 13 Senator Richard Shelby, Shelby Opposes Massive New Regulator and Taxpayer Exposure in Housing Regulation Bill (May 15, 2014), available at http://www.shelby.senate.gov/public/index.cfm/ newsreleases?ID=50559536-37c2-41d4-9067-09894d4477ab. 15 Senator Richard Shelby, The Danger of an Unaccountable ‘Consumer-Protection’ Czar, Wall Street Journal (July 21, 2011), available at http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB1000142405 3111903554904576457931310814462. 14 H.R. 2767 (the “Protecting American Taxpayers and Homeowners Act of 2013”), available at https://www.congress.gov/113/bills/ hr2767/BILLS-113hr2767ih.pdf. 16 James Freeman, What If Republicans Win?, Wall Street Journal (Oct. 17, 2014), available at http://online.wsj.com/articles/theweekend-interview-what-if-republicans-win-1413585182. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 N E W YO R K WA S H I N GTO N PA R I S BRUSSELS LO N D O N MOSCOW FRANKFURT C O LO G N E ROME MILAN H O N G KO N G A leading international law firm with 16 offices located in major financial centers around the world, Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP has helped shape the globalization of the legal profession for more than 65 years. Our worldwide practice has a proven track record for innovation and providing work of the highest quality to meet the needs of our domestic and international clients. Cleary Gottlieb advises many of the largest and most systemically significant U.S. and non-U.S. banking entities in the world on the full range of banking, securities and related regulatory matters. BEIJING BUENOS AIRES S Ã O PA U LO ABU DHABI SEOUL clearygottlieb.com The Art of the Possible: Prospects for Financial Services Legislation in the 114th Congress almost certainly direct at least one legislative broadside at the governance, funding, and operation of the CFPB. That sort of legislation is very unlikely to make it through to enactment, however. In addition to viewing the Dodd-Frank Act as a hindrance to economic growth, House Republicans generally remain skeptical that the law has achieved (or will ever achieve) its stated objectives of ensuring financial stability and ending “too-big-to-fail.” The latter concern has been a particular focus of committee activity under Chairman Hensarling. On the fouryear anniversary of the Act’s enactment, committee ‘‘ Proposals to raise or otherwise modify the SIFI asset threshold have already been endorsed on a bipartisan basis in the House and appear to be gaining support in the Senate. Republicans issued a staff report concluding that “not only did the Dodd-Frank Act not end ‘too-big-to-fail,’ it had the opposite effect of further entrenching it as official government policy.”17 In particular, the report’s authors cast doubt on the credibility of the resolution plans (or “living wills”) mandated under Dodd-Frank and allege that, rather than ending “too-big-to-fail” (TBTF) the Orderly Liquidation Authority (OLA), codified in Title II of Dodd-Frank, has become a “fixture in the regulators’ 17 Failing to End “Too Big to Fail”: An Assessment of the DoddFrank Act Four Years Later, Report Prepared by the Republican Staff of the Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives (July 2014), available at http://financialservices. house.gov/uploadedfiles/071814_tbtf_report_final.pdf. 56 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 toolkit, . . . subverting market discipline and making future bail-outs more (not less) likely.”18 Chairman Hensarling has pledged to pursue a package of TBTF-related provisions,19 potentially including the repeal of the OLA, various FSOC-related measures, and additional limits on the Federal Reserve’s “lender of last resort” authority. The proposed repeal of the OLA could conceivably be joined with a broader proposal, now pending in the House Judiciary Committee, to modify the Bankruptcy Code to facilitate the orderly resolution of large financial institutions. Financial Services Legislation That Could Advance in the New Congress So exactly what kind of targeted banking legislation might advance in the new Congress? The leading contenders for now appear to be proposals to modify the current statutory threshold of $50 billion in total assets at which bank holding companies become subject to “enhanced prudential standards” (regarding capital, liquidity, risk-management) and regulation as “systemically-important financial institutions” (SIFIs).20 Proposals to raise or otherwise modify the SIFI asset threshold have already been endorsed on a bipartisan basis in the House21 and appear to be gaining support in the Senate. Senior regulators have also expressed support for revisiting the SIFI threshold. Most notably, Governor Dan Tarullo has proposed raising the threshold to $100 billion, arguing that mandatory resolution planning, 18 Id, at 59-60. 19 Jeb Hensarling, Chairman, House Financial Services Committee, Dodd-Frank Results in Less Freedom, Less Opportunity and a Less Dynamic Economy, Remarks at a Mercatus Center-CATO Institute Conference (July 16, 2014), available at http://financialservices. house.gov/news/documentsingle.aspx?DocumentID=388236. “Our Committee will also soon take legislative action to end DoddFrank’s bailout fund and bring to an end the reign of those that are to Too Big to Fail.” 20 Dodd-Frank Act § 165(a)(1) 21 H.R. 4060 (the “Systemic Risk Designation Improvement Act of 2014), available at https://www.congress.gov/113/bills/hr4060/ BILLS-113hr4060ih.pdf and H.R. 4532, available at https://www. congress.gov/113/bills/hr4532/BILLS-113hr4532ih.pdf. stress-testing and other regulations “do not seem . . . to be necessary” for banks with between $50 billion and $100 billion in total assets.22 Similarly, Comptroller of the Currency Tom Curry has questioned the utility of the $50 billion “bright line,” and has suggested that a more sensible approach would be to “use an asset figure as a first screen and give discretion to the supervisors based on the risks in their business plan and operations.”23 Even former Rep. Barney Frank recently endorsed the concept in testimony before the committee he previously chaired.24 Modifying the SIFI size threshold has recently been the focus of a legislative effort in the House Financial Services Committee, where two leading proposals have been considered. The first, a bill sponsored by Rep. Blaine Luetkemeyer (R-MO)25 and co-sponsored by 77 others (58 Republicans and 19 Democrats), would eliminate the automatic asset threshold altogether and instead require the FSOC to apply an “indicator-based measurement approach,” which considers several factors in addition to size, to assess systemic importance. A second bill,26 authored by Rep. Joyce Beatty (D-OH) and co-sponsored by Rep. Steve Stivers (R-OH), would direct the FSOC to review banks with total assets of between $50 billion and $250 billion in order to determine whether to subject these firms to enhanced prudential standards and supervision, and expresses the “sense of Congress that consolidated asset size remains a factor, but only one of many factors, that should be considered in determining 22 Daniel K. Tarullo, Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Rethinking the Aims of Prudential Regulation, Remarks at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Bank Structure Conference, Chicago, IL (May 8, 2014), available at http://www. federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/tarullo20140508a.pdf. 23 Rachel Witkowski, Curry: $50B Cutoff Alone Is Inadequate to Gauge Banks’ Risk, American Banker (Sept. 23, 2014), available at http://www.americanbanker.com/issues/179_184/curry-50bcutoff-alone-is-inadequate-to-gauge-banks-risk-1070157-1.html. 24 House Financial Services Committee, Hearing Entitled “Assessing the Impact of the Dodd-Frank Act Four Years Later” (July 23, 2014), available at http://financialservices.house.gov/calendar/ eventsingle.aspx?EventID=388239. systemic risk.”27 Although these legislative proposals did not make it out of committee during this Congress, they seem to underscore a growing, bipartisan consensus that Congress should revisit the SIFI threshold. While no comparable legislation has advanced to date in the Senate, the idea of raising the SIFI threshold has begun to garner some interest on both sides of the aisle. Notably, Sen. Sherrod Brown (D-OH), who could serve as the Ranking Minority Member on the Banking Committee next year, has criticized the $50 billion asset threshold as an approach that treats regional banks operating under a “traditional banking model” whose failure would not “threaten the U.S. or global financial system” the same as larger, more complex institutions.28 In addition, he has underscored the need for regulators to examine the systemic risk posed by banks’ size, leverage, and business model on a case-by-case basis and to “strike the right balance between identifying institutions and activities that present the most risk.”29 With lawmakers and regulators alike now acknowledging that the contours of the SIFI universe, as defined in Dodd-Frank, are overly broad, it may be possible for legislation amending the SIFI threshold to advance in the new Congress, to serve as a vehicle for advancing targeted relief for smaller banks, and potentially to include additional provisions that could provide some limited relief for larger banks (e.g., with respect to the Dodd-Frank derivatives “push-out” requirement). It is also possible that various “FSOC reform” proposals could find their way into such a legislative package. One possible starting point for a bipartisan discussion in the Senate regarding possible amendments to DoddFrank might be legislation Senator Shelby introduced in early 2013 consisting exclusively of purely technical 27 Id, at 12. 25 H.R. 4060. 28 Senate Banking Committee, Hearing Entitled “What Makes A Bank Systemically Important?” (July 16, 2014), available at http:// www.banking.senate.gov/public/index.cfm?FuseAction=Hearings. Hearing&Hearing_ID=7d743184-d3e5-4ee7-8d41ab4d846f7457. 26 H.R. 4532. 29 Id. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 57 The Art of the Possible: Prospects for Financial Services Legislation in the 114th Congress corrections to Dodd-Frank (e.g., statutory typos, imprecise cross-references, etc.).30 Governor Tarullo has proposed tailoring existing and forthcoming regulatory requirements according to banks’ size, scope, and range of activities, noting that certain existing regulatory requirements may be “disproportionately costly for community banks.”31 He has also suggested that it may be “worthwhile to have a policy discussion of statutes that might be amended explicitly to exclude community banks” with less than $10 billion in total assets, particularly citing the Volcker Rule and the incentive compensation requirements imposed under Sec. 956 of the Dodd-Frank Act.32 Both of these suggestions could also find their way into new legislation. Finally, there is a substantial risk that financial services legislation – in particular, punitive measures targeting the largest banks – could advance in the Senate outside of the committee process, especially if incoming Majority Leader Mitch McConnell (R-KY) follows through on his pledge to provide for a “free and open amendment process” on the Senate floor.33 The Congressional Bully Pulpit Even if a two-year legislative stalemate ensues, the new Republican-controlled Congress will nonetheless have a significant impact on financial services regulation and policy through use of the “bully pulpit” that Congressional oversight confers. This can be an especially influential platform when the same party controls both chambers of Congress and could be particularly significant with respect to the regulatory agencies’ ongoing implementation of Dodd-Frank. 30 S.451 (the “Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Technical Corrections Act of 2013”), available at https://www.congress.gov/113/bills/s451/BILLS-113s451is.pdf. 31 Tarullo, at 13. 32 Id, at 11. 33 Sarah Mimms, What to Expect From Mitch McConnell’s Senate, National Journal (Nov. 5, 2014), available at http://www. nationaljournal.com/congress/what-to-expect-from-mitchmcconnell-s-senate-20141105. 58 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 In addition to jaw-boning regulators to tailor the application of automatic SIFI regulation for covered insurance companies and smaller banks, the Republicanled oversight committees are likely to weigh in on implementation of the Volcker Rule. Indeed, the current Congress was instrumental in pressuring the regulators to adopt special rules regarding the application of the Volcker Rule to certain collateralized debt obligations,34 and it seems likely this trend will continue in the new Congress, especially in light of the approaching expiration of the Volcker Rule “conformance period.” For example, the House has passed legislation addressing the treatment of certain collateralized loan obligations (CLOs) on three different occasions, once on a stand-alone basis and twice coupled with separate policy proposals, clarifying that the Volcker Rule does not require banking organizations to divest, prior to July 21, 2017, CLO debt securities issued before Jan. 31, 2014.35 In what may constitute the nascent stage of another bipartisan Volcker Rule-related initiative on Capitol Hill, three Democrats on the House Financial Services Committee – Gary Peters (MI), John Carney, Jr. (DE), and Dennis Heck (WA) – recently sent a letter urging the Federal Reserve to “streamline the process” for banking entities to avail themselves of the seven-year conformance period for certain investments in legacy venture capital and private equity funds.36 As the July 21, 2015 expiration of the existing conformance period approaches, the new Congress is likely to be 34 Joint Press Release, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Commodity Futures Trading Commission, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, Securities and Exchange Commission, Agencies Approve Interim Final Rule Authorizing Retention of Interests in and Sponsorship of Collateralized Debt Obligations Backed Primarily by Bank-Issued Trust Preferred Securities (Jan. 14, 2014), available at http:// federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/bcreg/20140114b.htm. 35 See H.R. 4167 (the “Restoring Proven Financing for American Employers Act”), available at https://www.congress.gov/113/ bills/hr4167/BILLS-113hr4167rfs.pdf; H.R. 5405 (the “Promoting Job Creation and Reducing Small Business Burdens Act”), available at https://www.congress.gov/113/bills/hr5405/BILLS113hr5405rfs.pdf, and H.R. 5461, available at https://www. congress.gov/113/bills/hr5461/BILLS-113hr5461rfs.pdf. 36 Letter from Representatives Gary Peters, John Carney, Jr., and Dennis Heck, Members, House Financial Services Committee, to Scott Alvarez, General Counsel, Federal Reserve Board (Aug. 7, 2014). The Art of the Possible: Prospects for Financial Services Legislation in the 114th Congress active on Volcker Rule-related issues both in an oversight capacity and potentially through new legislation. Executive Branch Nominations Finally, the Senate’s new Republican majority is sure to have a significant impact on both pending and forthcoming executive branch nominations, with President Obama’s nominees likely to face even greater scrutiny. As a result of Senate Majority Leader Harry Reid’s (D-NV) invocation of the so-called “nuclear option” in November 2013, only a simple majority, rather than a filibuster-proof 60-vote super majority, is now ‘‘ A complete and utter government stalemate is not in anyone’s enlightened self-interest – neither that of the country as a whole, nor that of a president contemplating his second-term legacy, nor that of the incoming Republican majority on Capitol Hill. needed to confirm most executive branch nominations, a rule change the incoming GOP majority seems unlikely to revisit (although they decried the change at the time). This new dynamic is likely to be on display early in the new Congress, when the Senate will consider the president’s nominees to fill several significant positions at the Treasury Department and on the Federal Reserve Board. 60 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Conclusion The next two years in Washington are certain to be replete with partisan skirmishing – no doubt about that. And chances are that, before the 114th Congress has adjourned, President Obama will have used his veto pen on more than one occasion. Yet, a complete and utter government stalemate is not in anyone’s enlightened self-interest – neither that of the country as a whole, nor that of a president contemplating his second-term legacy, nor that of the incoming Republican majority on Capitol Hill. House Majority Leader Kevin McCarthy (R-CA) was recently quoted in the press as saying “I do know this ... If we don’t capture the House stronger, and the Senate, and prove we can govern, there won’t be a Republican president in 2016.”37 Similarly, on election night, Senator Mitch McConnell struck a similar tone, arguing that Republicans and Democrats “have an obligation to work together on issues where we can agree.”38 Clearly, Democrats and Republicans will seek to distinguish themselves and their political philosophies and agendas in advance of the 2016 elections, and some of that will likely spill over into financial services legislation. But there will also be opportunities for targeted, incremental financial services legislation to advance in the next Congress, especially if lawmakers from both parties begin to coalesce around targeted fixes, such as those described above. 37 Jake Sherman, Exclusive: Kevin McCarthy vows change on Hill to save GOP, POLITICO (Oct. 26, 2014), available at http:// www.politico.com/story/2014/10/kevin-mccarthy-congressrepublicans-112209.html. 38 Alexander Burns, GOP takes control of Senate in midterm rout, POLITICO (Nov. 4, 2014), available at http://www.politico.com/ story/2014/11/election-update-midterms-2014-house-senateraces-112491.html?hp=f1. Life’s better when we’re connected to growth to vision to jobs At Bank of America, we’re connecting local businesses across the country with the resources and support they need to grow, hire and fuel their local economy. Because when local businesses thrive, the whole community gets stronger. See how we’re helping local businesses at bankofamerica.com/local to each other Bank of America, N.A. Member FDIC. © 2013 Bank of America Corporation. ARHMSJB3 Margin for Error Balancing the Risks and Benefits of Uncleared Swaps T by D onna Parisi, Partner, and Barnabas Reynolds, Partner, Shearman & Sterling LLP To ensure that systemic concerns arising from counterparty risks associated with uncleared derivatives are sufficiently managed through collateral, the G20 added margin requirements for such derivatives to the list of post credit crunch reforms in July 2011. The rules are designed to reduce counterparty credit risk, limit contagion, and incentivize the central clearing of derivatives trades. The reliance on collateral rather than capital charges to achieve these goals ensures that the defaulting party bears the loss, rather than the performing counterparty. The uncleared over-the-counter space, however, will continue to be very sizeable given that many derivatives are ineligible for central clearing due to insufficient standardization or liquidity, or because of valuation challenges. The rules, focusing on the bilateral exchange of margin, could potentially fuel negative outcomes such as regulatory arbitrage and put yet more pressure on sourcing good quality collateral, which could in turn create space for lessregulated entities to occupy. Further, the proposed new rules threaten to introduce new forms of legal uncertainty into the cross-border transactional environment, some of which are very significant indeed and not easy to mitigate. 62 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 International Initiatives In September 2013, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision and International Organization of Securities Commissions released their final framework for margin requirements for non-centrally cleared derivatives transactions.1 The framework sets out eight key principles and aims to ensure harmonization of their implementation across multiple jurisdictions. While the final framework is not binding on any regulatory authorities, it informs the approach of national regulators as they adopt their respective margin regimes. regulators, the proposed rules would apply to all non-centrally cleared swap activity2 (i.e., swaps and security-based swaps) without reference to whether the registrant’s status relates to transactions in one or both swap product categories.3 The BCBS-IOSCO rules require the bilateral exchange of initial margin (IM) and the delivery by one party to the other of variation margin (VM) and apply to financial firms and systemically important non-financial entities (“covered entities”), the definitions for which are left to national regulation. In Europe, draft regulatory technical standards, closely following BCBS-IOSCO and implementing the relevant provisions of the European Market Infrastructure Regulation were published by the European Supervisory Authorities for comment in April 2014 and are expected to be finalized by the end of the year. In September 2014, U.S. banking regulators and the Commodity Futures Trading Commission took steps to adopt revised rule proposals modeled closely on the BCBS-IOSCO framework that would apply to swap registrants under their respective remits. In the case of swap registrants subject to the jurisdiction of any of the U.S. banking 1 IOSCO recently published a consultation on proposed risk mitigation techniques (apart from margin) for uncleared derivatives. The proposals would apply to the same covered entities as the margin requirements and aim to facilitate the management of counterparty credit risk and to increase legal certainty. The proposals are broadly similar to the rules already implemented in the E.U. and the U.S. However, there are some key differences. For example, the trade confirmation requirements apply to non-systemically important non-financial counterparties in the E.U. but not in the U.S. There are also differences between the U.S. and E.U. approach to the material terms that need to be reconciled. Differences in implementation across jurisdictions may create compliance issues and the industry will need to have robust systems in place to capture all jurisdictional requirements. 2 The CFTC proposed rulemaking would expand the definition of “cleared swap” to include swaps that are cleared by certain clearing organizations not registered with the CFTC as a “derivatives clearing organization.” Failure to adequately revise this definition could lead to serious market fragmentation or disruption as persons subject to the CFTC’s swaps requirements could potentially remain subject to the U.S. margin regime for uncleared swaps for a swap cleared at a clearing organization that is not a registered derivatives clearing organization. The CFTC requested comment on this point. 3 As used in this article, the term “swap” refers to both swaps and security-based swaps. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 63 Margin for Error: Balancing the Risks and Benefits of Uncleared Swaps Key Aspects of the Margin Requirements Parties Subject to the Obligations BCBS-IOSCO U.S. E.U. Financial firms Swap dealers Financial counterparties Systemically important non-financial entities Security-based swap dealers IM obligations apply when a covered entity’s gross notional outstanding group exposure exceeds €8 billion. Major swap participants Non-financial counterparties that exceed the EMIR clearing thresholds. The clearing thresholds, in gross notional value, are €1 billion for credit and equity derivatives and €3 billion for interest rate swaps, foreign exchange, commodity and other OTC derivatives. Major security-based swap participants (each, a “swap registrant”). IM margin requirements apply to transactions between swap registrants as well as a swap registrant and a financial end-user where the financial end-user has an aggregate gross notional exposure under all its uncleared swaps (including foreign exchange swaps and forwards) exceeding $3 billion. VM obligations apply even where the financial end-user’s exposure does not exceed the $3 billion threshold. IM requirements only apply if the €8 billion threshold is reached. A quirk of the E.U. proposal, as drafted, is that it appears to apply to all non-E.U. non-financial entities, whereas E.U. corporates are only within scope if they exceed the EMIR clearing threshold. Margin obligations are not mandatory for transactions involving non-financial end users.1 Transactions Within Scope Non-centrally cleared derivative transactions between two covered entities, except for physically settled foreign exchange swaps and forwards. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework, except that the exemption for physically settled foreign exchange swaps and forwards only applies to IM requirements. Bilateral Exchange of Margin IM to be posted gross on a counterparty portfolio basis and on a bankruptcy-remote basis. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework.3 Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework. Requirement for bankruptcy-remote posting of IM prevents continuation of E.U. market practice for title transfer, introducing significant new legal uncertainties surrounding the less developed classes of security interest (including “pledge”). Deadline for Implementation4 IM requirements phased-in from December 1, 2015 to December 1, 2019. From December 1, 2019, IM required where gross notional outstanding group exposure exceeds €8 billion. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework. VM may be posted net, and must be posted with sufficient frequency (e.g. daily).2 Compliance with VM requirements as of December 1, 2015. Only applies to contracts entered into after the applicable date. Re-hypothecation of Margin Cash and non-cash VM may be re-hypothecated. IM should not be re-hypothecated except in limited circumstances and may only be re-hypothecated once. Same as BCBS-IOSCO save that the re-hypothecation of IM will be prohibited. Same as BCBS-IOSCO save that the re-hypothecation of IM will be prohibited. De Minimis Thresholds De minimis threshold for IM of €50 million (c. $65 million) on a group consolidated basis for all uncleared derivatives between two consolidated groups. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework. No threshold for VM. De minimis minimum transfer amount of €500,000. The feasibility of allocating the IM threshold across entities within a corporate group remains uncertain. 64 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Calibration of Margin BCBS-IOSCO U.S. E.U. IM calculated using either a quantitative portfolio or a standardized margin schedule. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework but specify a one- to five-year historical observation period. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework except that those using internal models must input data covering a minimum period of three years. Exposures within designated risk categories can be netted prior to calculating the required margin. The calibration of IM is based on what is required, at 99 percent confidence levels, for liquidation of a position over a 10-day horizon using historical data. The data must incorporate a five-year stress period. IM models subject to quantitative and qualitative requirements. The U.S. banking regulators propose articulated standards similar to those required for proprietary models used for internal regulatory capital monitoring purposes. Dispute mechanisms required for differences between models. Inter-Affiliate Transactions Defers to local rule-makers to determine application. No exemption for inter-affiliate swaps, which raises concerns about the ability of corporate groups to pursue internal risk management strategies. Intra-group transactions in a financial or non-financial group are exempt provided certain conditions are met. Financial groups need approval of regulator. Exempt Entities Sovereigns, central banks, multilateral development banks, the Bank for International Settlements and non-systemic non-financial firms. Transactions between a covered entity and an exempt entity are exempt. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework. Same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework but includes an exemption for covered bond issuers, recognizing that they are not set up to post margin. Eligible Collateral for Margin National regulators to develop list of eligible assets. Examples include cash, government and central bank securities, corporate bonds, covered bonds, equities, and gold. Assets to be highly liquid and, after appropriate haircuts are applied, able to hold their value in a time of financial stress. Collateral should not include securities issued by the counterparty or its related entities. Generally the same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework. Generally the same as the BCBS-IOSCO framework, except that the use of senior securitization tranches and units in retail funds known as undertakings for the collective investment in transferable securities (“UCITS”) is permitted, which will likely require larger haircuts while reducing pressure on government bonds. Securities issued by financial institutions not eligible. Additional haircut of 8 percent for currency mismatch. Securities issued by financial institutions not eligible. Additional haircut of 8 percent for currency mismatch. 4 For swaps with non-financial end users, the proposed rulemaking of the U.S. banking regulators would require swap registrants to collect IM or VM only at such times and in such forms as the registrant determines appropriate to address the registrant’s credit risk to the counterparty. On the other hand, the CFTC proposal includes no margin collection requirement for swaps with a non-financial end-user. Swap registrants subject to the CFTC’s margin framework would be required to calculate on a daily basis a hypothetical IM and VM amount related to such swaps where it has material swaps exposure as a risk management measure. The CFTC also proposes additional trading relationship documentation requirements whereby the governing agreement must specify whether IM or VM will be exchanged, transaction valuation methodology and data sources for such purpose as well as provide for dispute resolution mechanics. The divergent approaches stem from the CFTC’s adherence to pronouncements of the U.S. Congress that non-financial end-users should not be required to post margin for their swaps, and a strict construction by the U.S. banking regulators of their legislative mandate to adopt margin requirements for the uncleared swap activity of swap registrants under their jurisdiction. 5 Daily bilateral exchange of VM is likely to prove to be an operationally challenging task for smaller entities and trades across time zones and may trigger heightened sensitivity among market participants to liquidity management concerns. 6 Note, however, that for purposes of calculating the minimum amount of required IM, the U.S. proposals permit the use of models that take into account offsetting exposures, diversification, and other hedging benefits for uncleared swaps governed by the same master netting agreement by reference to empirical correlations within – but not across – specified risk categories. 7 While the EU and U.S. proposals do not require compliance for transactions executed prior to the relevant compliance date, as a practical matter, the margin requirements will apply retroactively to the extent entities covered by the rules calculate their margin requirements on a portfolio basis under an eligible master netting agreement that governs transactions executed both prior to and after the effective date of the rules. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 65 Margin for Error: Balancing the Risks and Benefits of Uncleared Swaps Impact The introduction of the requirements presents significant commercial, operational, and legal challenges. Availability of Collateral There are concerns that stricter margin requirements may have a significant impact on market liquidity and the availability of collateral, particularly as IM must be posted gross and cannot be netted or offset between counterparties. Several quantitative impact studies have been conducted. An analysis conducted by the International Swaps and Derivatives Association ‘‘ There are concerns that stricter margin requirements may have a significant impact on market liquidity and the availability of collateral. estimates that the earlier versions of the BCBSIOSCO framework could see IM requirements reach a peak of $10.2 trillion (c. €8.04 trillion) if internal models were not used to make IM calculations and no counterparty threshold applied. On the other hand, a study referenced by BCBS-IOSCO projects that model-based IM calculations could result in requirements of approximately €1.3 trillion where no counterparty threshold applies and nearly €600 billion if a counterparty threshold of €50 million applies. These estimations rise dramatically to €7.5 trillion and €6.2 trillion, respectively, where calculations are entirely based on a standardized margin schedule. 66 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Rise in Shadow Banking Activity Given the demand for eligible collateral, the cost of such collateral is likely to rise. Market participants will look to exchange non-qualifying securities for eligible collateral. This collateral transformation activity will increase repo and securities lending activity, which will partly be absorbed within the shadow banking sector. The CFTC has acknowledged that collateral transformation services might proliferate, but does not mention the potential risks that this might give rise to. Moreover, the traditional repo market is under pressure from Basel III reforms (notably the leverage ratio and the Net Stable Funding Ratio). Regulators are taking steps to curb risk in the shadow banking arena. The Financial Stability Board recently published its final framework for haircuts on collateral in uncleared securities financing transactions, as a measure to thwart the rapid onset of margin calls. The framework is made up of qualitative standards for methodologies to calculate haircuts on collateral received and proposed numerical haircut floors in which financing against collateral other than certain government securities is provided to nonbanks. The proposed implementation date by national authorities is the end of 2017. There will be significant challenges in implementation, given that in the U.S. regulation is split among various regulatory agencies and more entity-based (for instance, by banks, broker-dealers, systemically important financial institutions, and asset managers) as opposed to activitybased as it is in Europe. Infrastructure Needs Robust systems for the calculation and notification of margin amounts will be required.8 In addition, new infrastructure and technology will need to be developed 8 In this regard, the U.S. proposed rules require a swap registrant to calculate IM and VM not only for transactions subject to the margin requirements but also hypothetical IM and VM amounts for positions held by non-financial entities that have material swap exposure to the swap registrant and compare these hypothetical requirements to actual requirements. Thus, margin calculations will apply to a broad swath of a swap registrant’s counterparties, even if a counterparty is not ultimately required to post margin. A leader in serving the global financial services marketplace With a global presence and industry-focused advice, EY’s nearly 35,000 financial services professionals provide high-quality assurance, tax, transaction and advisory services, including operations, process improvement, risk and technology to financial services companies worldwide. © 2014 EYGM Limited. All Rights Reserved. For more information, visit ey.com. Margin for Error: Balancing the Risks and Benefits of Uncleared Swaps to facilitate the allocation and monitoring of the €50 million/$65 million threshold across legal entities. Likewise, it is imperative that the industry adopt and receive necessary regulatory approval of a common methodology for the calculation of IM requirements to promote consistency and minimize the risk of disputes.9 In the absence of a consistent model, the bespoke calculation of margin amounts by each counterparty to a trade could result in different amounts being paid, by counterparties, due to legitimate variations between models. To this end, ISDA is leading an initiative to develop a standard IM model (SIMM) for widespread use by the market. The advantages of this would include greater predictability in margin requirements. For pension plans, this may significantly affect fund performance and the funding of pension obligations. Predictability of margin requirements is critical to the consistent pricing of transactions and discouragement of aggressive models to win business. There are also different views regarding margin funding costs, with some institutions pricing on the basis of the term of the transaction and others on an expected or average life assumption. Another potential area of inconsistency is the placement of transactions into risk categories, which has netting implications as described above. Under the U.S. proposals, each covered entity selects the risk category for netting purposes. This may lead to disparate results where two swap registrants are party to a trade. Commercial Concerns There have been a number of commercial concerns raised by market participants. Financial end-users with directional portfolios such as pension plans will not benefit from the limited permitted exposure netting within risk categories (see Calibration of Margin row in the table) resulting in higher IM for those end users. ‘‘ Predictability of margin requirements is critical to the consistent pricing of transactions and discouragement of aggressive models to win business. 9 68 The U.S. proposals reflect an expectation that regulators in multiple jurisdictions will adopt similar requirements for noncentrally cleared derivatives and contemplate adoption of a framework permitting non-U.S. swap registrants to comply with U.S. requirements through compliance with the requirements of another jurisdiction whose margin regime for non-centrally cleared derivatives is found by U.S. authorities to be comparable to equivalent U.S. rules. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 The scope of the rules is wide and extends margin requirements to securitization vehicles, an arguably unnecessary reach of the rules given the priority swap counterparties have in securitization payment waterfalls over and above bond investors. (But it is likely that many securitizations would fall below the $3 billion threshold). This is yet another cost constraint on securitization structures and does not serve to encourage the assetbacked security market, which is an essential pillar for the full-scale rehabilitation and normalization of the commercial and retail banking market globally. Under the E.U. proposals, securitization issuers would also fall outside scope if the swap exposure of the issuer is less than the €8 billion threshold. There is also a specific exemption for covered bond issuers. Finally, the U.S. regulators have acknowledged that there may be a discrepancy between the classification of a counterparty as a non-financial entity for purposes of determining eligibility for the mandatory clearing exemption and classification as a non-financial end-user for the uncleared margin requirements. The discrepancy does not arise in the E.U. context as the end-user exemption from clearing is aligned with the exemption from margin requirements. Under the U.S. proposals, the clearing exemption for end users could well become irrelevant given that margin for uncleared trades is likely to be higher than for the cleared counterparty, which in turn would steer those end users, falling within the clearing exemption but within the scope of the margin rules, to the cleared space. This outcome would not be aligned with the valid reasons justifying the end-user exemption from central clearing. A separate significant issue facing U.S. covered entities is the absence of an exemption for intra-group transactions. E.U. entities benefit from such an exemption. The divergence increases the potential for arbitrage. This issue is entwined with resolution and recovery planning and has implications from a regulatory capital perspective. To guard against the risk that their security may become void or unenforceable, counterparties will need to undertake an analysis of relevant local laws on security interests, and manage their practical arrangements carefully. This of course is likely to involve some uncertainties, difficult judgment calls (and the running of risk) and considerable expense. The E.U. proposals also require a legal opinion verifying that IM is adequately segregated and insulated from the bankruptcy risk of the collateral taker. Where IM is in the form of cash, the cash amount will need to be individually segregated per each collateral provider with a third party bank (to whose credit risk the provider is then exposed). ‘‘ Increased Legal Risk and Additional Documentation Requirements There are certain legal risk issues that have not been sufficiently acknowledged or addressed in either of the proposed U.S. or E.U. rules. As mentioned, IM will have to be exchanged two-way and gross on a bankruptcyremote basis, and be immediately available to the collateral taker. The U.S. proposals require the use of third-party custodial accounts for cash and securities, buttressed by a security interest or pledge in favor of the collateral taker. In the E.U., title transfer arrangements, which currently predominate in the market, will not meet the requirement that margin be held on a bankruptcy-remote basis. The margin will have to be held on a security interest basis and held either with the collateral provider or with a custodian. E.U. laws on security interest arrangements are not well developed and are inadequately harmonized across the E.U. The E.U. requires collateral to be in the “possession or control” of the collateral taker to get full protection from normal insolvency law. The English courts interpret this as potentially prohibiting the collateral provider from automatically withdrawing collateral deemed no longer necessary. So U.S. arrangements where the collateral provider periodically takes back from the collateral account excess collateral can present issues in the E.U., which seeks to protect the collateral taker to a greater degree. The market will no doubt use the U.S. style arrangements globally if at all possible to avoid paying in IM for longer than required and to avoid having to wait for a collateral taker to release reimbursement. There are certain legal risk issues that have not been sufficiently acknowledged or addressed in either of the proposed U.S. or E.U. rules. With respect to third party custodial arrangements, custody agreements and account control agreements will need to be negotiated and put in place with a large contingent of counterparties. Existing documentation will need to be modified to contemplate these third party arrangements. Documentation may also need to be amended to comply with proposed CFTC rules requiring that swap trading relationship documentation include a process for determining the value of each swap in compliance with the margin requirements.10 It 10 Existing CFTC Regulation 23.504(b) requires a swap registrant to include in its swap trading relationship documentation methods and procedures agreed with its counterparty for the valuation of every swap at any time from execution to termination, maturity, or expiration of the relevant swap. The explicit objective of the regulation is facilitation of compliance with each of the CFTC’s risk management and margin requirements for swap registrants. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 69 Margin for Error: Balancing the Risks and Benefits of Uncleared Swaps remains to be seen what this disclosure requirement will mean in practice, especially with respect to proprietary risk based margin models. This rule, as is the case elsewhere, also requires that each swap registrant establish and maintain policies and procedures to resolve a valuation discrepancy, including as to how VM will be handled pending resolution of a dispute. Additionally, an institution may wish to put in place separate master netting agreements to avoid having the margin requirements apply to pre-effective date transactions since IM and VM requirements will apply to all transactions under a master netting agreement that governs post-effective date transactions. From a risk perspective, while holding collateral with a custodian mitigates the risk associated with the collateral receiver’s bankruptcy, it does not eliminate all risk. In the event of an insolvency of counterparty (or other trigger for the release of collateral) it may well be that a custodian will not release the collateral to either party until directed to do so by a court with competent jurisdiction. It is also critical to keep in mind that in times of systemic stress, liquidity may be severely impaired. Additionally, upon any custodian insolvency, excluding cash collateral from the bankruptcy estate is very difficult. This requires the reinvestment of cash into securities on a daily sweep basis generally. In the E.U., or at least in the U.K., banks holding cash collateral could recognize the beneficial interest of the custodian’s client in the cash (strictly the custodian’s rights as depositor to the cash account). More broadly, as greater amounts of collateral are held in a limited number of custodian banks, this will concentrate risk in the financial system further. Unless global regulators look again at permitting title transfer, the netting of IM payments, and expanding the list of eligible collateral, the effect of the rules for IM may simply be to swap counterparty risk for legal risk and uncertainty at an international level. Extraterritorial Application Another chief concern is the extraterritorial application of the regime for cross-border transactions, potentially leading to conflicts in the detailed application 70 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 of the regime at a local level. A key principle included in the BCBS-IOSCO framework is that national regulatory regimes implementing the framework should not lead to conflicting, duplicative, or inconsistent requirements for participants; should limit regulatory arbitrage; and should maintain a level playing field. Both the E.U. and the U.S. proposed rules allow for substituted compliance, or compliance with home country requirements through compliance with local rules, provided that the relevant margin regime is found to be equivalent to their respective rules. Both sets of proposed rules also have extraterritorial reach, although the E.U. proposed rules are not as wide-reaching as the proposed U.S. rules. It remains to be seen how many equivalence or comparability determinations will be issued for the uncleared margin requirements. In the U.S., consensus has not been reached and much uncertainty remains as to the extraterritorial application of Title VII of Dodd Frank generally. This, combined with a lack of resources on the part of CFTC staff to conduct comparability assessments, does not give the market confidence that cross-border reconciliation of the uncleared margin requirements will be achieved. This is of immediate concern, especially given the rather short implementation date for the largest institutions—which generally have global businesses. The timeframe for implementation of the final rules by market participants is tight, especially for VM. Lack of harmonization across jurisdictions will compound implementation anxieties, create uncertainty and increase legal risk. As with many of the reforms in response to the recent financial crisis, there are unintended consequences to the introduction of the uncleared margin rules, some of which are immediately apparent and some of which will only become evident as industry begins its implementation. Unfortunately, these reforms may be pushed through too quickly without resolving the interpretational issues and legal uncertainties they create. Bank on Us. Many of the largest financial institutions in the world turn to Morrison & Foerster for advice on bank regulatory matters, including privacy, money laundering, commercial and retail banking, regulatory capital, and financing and M&A opportunities. For our financial services and financial institutions clients, business right now is anything but usual. Visit www.mofo.com/resources/regulatory-reform/ for information on our regulatory reform resources, including our proprietary FrankNDodd™ service. ©2014 Morrison & Foerster LLP, mofo.com By the Numbers 6 3 Billion $ Paid in income taxes by the U.S. banking industry last year.2 6.6% 94,549 The contribution of the U.S. financial sector to GDP.3 The number of bank branches in the U.S.1 2Million 5 0 Billion The number of individuals employed by TCH Owner Banks globally.4 $ The total U.S. banks paid to shareholders last year.5 2,500 $ .7 1 0 Trillion The median amount spent by banks and finance organizations per employee on cybersecurity. $ The total deposits held at U.S. commercial banks.6 400 $ 72 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 The median amount spent by retail and consumer products businesses per employee on cybersecurity.7 123Billion The number of transactions processed annually by U.S. banks. 80Trillion $ 5,757 The value of all annual transactions processed annually by U.S. banks.8 440,000 The number of commercial banks insured by the FDIC in the U.S.11 The number of ATMs in the U.S., the most of any country in the world.9 582 Billion $ 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 2 Billion . 5 The total amount loaned by U.S. banks to small businesses.10 TCH analysis. SNL Financial. TCH analysis. SNL Financial. Bureau of Economic Analysis. U.S. Department of Commerce. http://www.bea.gov/iTable/iTable. cfm?ReqID=51&step=1#reqid=51&step=51&isuri=1&5114=a&5102=5 TCH analysis. TCH analysis. SNL Financial. FDIC, Quarterly Banking Profile, 2nd Quarter 2014 http://www.pwc.com/en_US/us/increasing-it-ef- The number of billpayment transactions initiated by account holders through online banking websites or mobile bill-payment applications in the last reported year.12 8. 9. fectiveness/publications/assets/2014-us-state-ofcybercrime.pdf The Federal Reserve 2013 Payments Study. 19 December 2013. http://www.frbservices.org/files/ communications/pdf/research/2013_payments_ study_summary.pdf. Scuffham, Matt and David Henry, “Banks to be hit with Microsoft costs for running outdated ATMs,” Reuters. March 14, 2014. http://www.reuters.com/ article/2014/03/14/us-banks-atms-idUSBRE- A2D13D20140314 10. U.S. Small Business Administration, Quarterly Lending Bulletin, http://www.sba.gov/sites/default/ files/SBL_2013q4.pdf 11. FDIC, Quarterly Banking Profile, 2nd Quarter 2014 12. The Federal Reserve 2013 Payments Study. 19 December 2013. http://www.frbservices.org/files/ communications/pdf/research/2013_payments_ study_summary.pdf. Research Rundown Research Rundown provides a comprehensive overview of the most groundbreaking and noteworthy research on critical banking and payments issues and seeks to capture insights from academics, think tanks, and regulators that may well influence the design and implementation of the industry’s regulatory architecture. 74 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Funding Costs Financial Firms Less Risky than Other Industries. The authors compare size-related funding cost differentials across industries to determine how size affects the cost of funding. Using pricing data on credit default swaps and bonds over the period 2004 to 2013, the paper finds that credit spreads of financial firms are no more sensitive to size than those of non-financial firms. They find evidence that financial firms as a group, particularly banking firms, have lower average costs of borrowing compared with similar firms in other industries. This suggests that financial firms may be viewed as less risky compared to firms in other industries. The authors conclude that “too-big-to-fail subsidies may be overestimated if they do not take into account the lower borrowing costs of larger firms across a variety of industries.” Ahmed, Javed, Christopher Anderson and Rebecca Zarutskie (2014), “Are Borrowing Costs of Large Financial Firms Unusual?” mineo, Federal Reserve Board, Harvard Business School, (September). Lender of Last Resort Rethinking the Lender of Last Resort. As part of a series on the future design of lender of last resort (LOLR), Paul Tucker discusses criticism central banks face when they inject liquidity into the financial system. The author states that central bank criticism is about the “political economy” and such criticism serves as an “important challenge to the legitimacy” of central banks. He discusses the criticisms related to the LOLR function of central banks and contends that once central banks are “perceived as having overstepped the mark in bailing out bust institutions, critics look for overreach in their more overtly macroeconomic interventions.” Tucker asserts that this is currently the critique of the Fed in the U.S. The “most serious accusation” by critics of central bank aid to insolvent firms, he argues, is that this support reaches beyond the central bank’s “legal authority.” He attempts to demonstrate that when financial firms become “deeply reluctant to turn to the LOLR,” via the discount window, it leaves the financial system fragile in “ways that are hard for regulation to undo.” Tucker, Paul (2014), “The lender of last resort and modern central banking: principles and reconstruction,” BIS Papers, 79, (September). Anonymous Lending Important in Restoring Confidence. The authors argue that there is a missing ingredient in “Bagehot’s Dictum.” Walter Bagehot, a 19th century British journalist and economist, wrote that “in times of financial crisis central banks should lend freely to solvent depository institutions, only against good collateral and at interest rates that are high enough to dissuade those borrowers that are not genuinely in need.” The missing ingredient, according to the authors, is secrecy – three kinds in particular: (i) central bank lending, (ii) borrower identity, and (iii) presence of borrowing from the central bank in the borrower’s portfolio. Gorton, Gary and Guillermo Ordoñez (2014), “How Central Banks End Crises,” PIER Working Paper, 14-025, (September). Costs of Regulation Impact of Liquidity Regulation on Lending to NonFinancial Sector. The authors use the implementation of the Individual Liquidity Guidance (ILG) regulation in the UK in 2010 to investigate how banks respond to tighter liquidity regulation. Under this regulation, a subset of banks were required to hold a sufficient stock of high quality liquid assets (HQLA) to cover net outflows of liabilities under two stress scenarios lasting either 14 days or 3 months. The authors find that rather than adjusting the size of their balance sheet to meet tighter liquidity regulation, banks subject to the ILG altered the composition of their assets and liabilities. On the asset side, banks significantly increased the share of HQLA to total assets, and on the liability side, ILG banks increased funding from more stable deposits and decreased their reliance on less stable short-term Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 75 wholesale and non-UK funding. The authors do not find evidence that liquidity regulations have a negative impact on bank lending to the non-financial sector, either in terms of quantity or price of lending. They conclude that because the ILG significantly reduced intra-financial claims without having a measurable impact on the price or quantity of lending to the real economy, liquidity regulation could be a useful macroprudential tool. Banerjee, Ryan and Hitoshi Mio (2014), “The Impact of Liquidity Regulation on Banks,” BIS Working Papers, 470, (October). Using Cost-Benefit Analysis to Determine Capital Requirements. The author posits that: (i) bank regulators have used a process that he calls “norming” (i.e., choosing capital levels that weed out the worst banks but leave most banks untouched); (ii) norming is a bad way to regulate banks, as it produces excessively generous rules that allow most banks to take excessive risks; (iii) inadequate capitalization of banks contributed to the financial crisis of 2007-2008; and (iv) if regulators had been required to use cost-benefit analysis rather than norming, they would have issued stricter capital adequacy rules. Posner, Eric (2014), “How Do Bank Regulators Determine Capital Adequacy Requirements?” University of Chicago Coase-Sandor Institute for Law & Economics Research Paper, 698, (September). Imposing Basel III Liquidity Regulations Reduces Bank Lending. The authors look at the macroeconomic impact of introducing a minimum liquidity standard for banks on top of existing capital adequacy requirements. The authors find that imposing a liquidity requirement would: (i) lead to a steady-state decrease of about 3% in the amount of loans made; (ii) an increase in banks’ holdings of securities of at least 6%; (iii) a fall in the interest rate on securities of a few basis points; and (iv) a decline in output of about 0.3%. Covas, Francisco and John Driscoll (2014), “Bank Liquidity and Capital Regulation in General 76 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Equilibrium,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Board- Division of Monetary Affairs, (September). Cross-Border Banking Cross-Border Banking and Liquidity. The authors investigate global factors associated with bank capital flows. They create a model where global banks interact with local banks and find that local currency appreciation is associated with higher leverage of the banking sector, thereby providing a bridge between exchange rates and financial stability. Given the preeminent role of the U.S. dollar as the currency used to denominate debt contracts, the authors shed light on why dollar appreciation constitutes a tightening of global financial conditions and why financial crises are associated with dollar shortages. Bruno, Valentina and Hyun Song Shin (2014) “Crossborder banking and global liquidity,” BIS Working Papers, 248, (August). Regulating Cross-Border Bank Flows Lowers the Risk of Financial Crisis. Using data on bilateral cross-border bank flows from 31 sources to 76 recipient countries over 1995–2012, and combining this information with new data on various capital controls and prudential measures in these countries, the authors examine whether cross-border capital flows can be regulated by imposing capital account restrictions at both source and recipient country ends. They find that capital account restrictions (CARs) can significantly influence the volume of cross-border bank flows. Given the close connection between cross-border bank flows and risks to global financial stability, the authors suggest that “adoption of relevant CARs in boom times could help to dampen the procyclicality of these flows, thereby lowering the risk of systemic financial crises.” Ghosh, Atish, Mahvash Qureshi and Naotaka Sugawara (2014), “Regulating Capital Flows at Both Ends; Does it Work?” IMF Working Paper, 14, 188, (October). If only there was only a better way to help manage, control and sustain your resolution planning. There is. No matter how you view resolution planning, you’re looking at time and effort. And if you miss something, you could end up facing even more stringent requirements and restrictions. That’s where KPMG’s Resolution Planning Service and its enabling technologies come into play. We help you harness the power of data analytics to collect the information you need, provide analysis that addresses regulatory requirements, and—in the end—help you create a sustainable process. Which means you can spend less time on your compliance efforts and more time focusing on the other tasks on your list. Contact Christopher Dias at [email protected] kpmg.com Some or all of the services described herein may not be permissible for KPMG audit clients and their affiliates. © 2014 KPMG LLP, a Delaware limited liability partnership and the U.S. member firm of the KPMG network of independent member firms affiliated with KPMG International Cooperative (“KPMG International”), a Swiss entity. 140207 Payments Digital Currencies. The authors discuss recent developments in payment systems, specifically focusing on the emergence of privately developed, internetbased digital currencies. The article argues that the key innovation of digital currencies is found in the “distributed ledger” technology that allows a payment system to operate exclusively in a decentralized fashion, without any intermediaries such as banks. The authors contend that this key innovation represents a fundamental change in how payments can be made to work. The article also provides an overview of how digital currencies work, as well as how new currency is created. Ali, Robleh, John Barrdear, Roger Clews and James Southgate (2014), “Innovations in payment technologies and the emergence of digital currencies,” Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 2014 Q3. Non-banks in Retail Payments. CPMI finds a significant presence of nonbanks in all stages of the payment process and across different payment instruments. The study analyzes all activities in the payment chain, such as credit and debit cards, credit transfers, direct debits, checks, e-money products and remittances. The paper finds that while the role of nonbanks in retail payments is increasing, most nonbanks ultimately rely on the credit/debit transfer services provided by banks for their funds settlement. Ultimately, the paper concludes that competition from nonbanks is driving banks to offer more efficient or faster payment services, which suggests that properly managed cooperation and competition between banks and nonbanks could enhance the security and efficiency of retail payments to the benefit of end users. Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures (2014), “Non-banks in retail payments,” Bank for International Settlements, (September). Risk Management Market Risk and Internal Models. The Basel Committee presents results from the first of two trading book test portfolio exercises, which focused on the revised internal models-based approach for market risk and is based on hypothetical portfolios. The second exercise focuses on banks’ actual portfolios and is being conducted in parallel with the Basel III monitoring exercise. The Basel Committee reports that the hypothetical portfolio exercise on the internal models approach provided encouraging results supporting the new market risk framework. Over 40 banks from various jurisdictions were able to implement the requirements for internal models. Banks were able to leverage the existing risk systems and perform the computation for the new risk measures within two quarters of the publication of the consultative document. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2014), “Analysis of the trading book hypothetical portfolio exercise,” Bank for International Settlements, (September). How Credit Default Risk Affects Bank Lending? The authors find that: (i) an increase in provisioning decreases bank lending and economic activity; and (ii) banks decrease provisioning as a percentage of total bank assets as bank lending increases. Therefore, banks take on more risk during upswings by building up relatively low provisions while they build up more loan loss provisions during downswings. Pool, Sebastiaan, Leo de Haan and Jan Jacobs (2014), “Loan loss provisioning, bank credit and the real economy,” DNB Working Paper, 445, (October). Systemic Risk Structural GARCH Model Provides Earlier Signals of Financial Firm Distress. The authors propose a new model of volatility the authors call “Structural GARCH”, which they then apply to the leverage effect and systemic risk measurement. While normal GARCH models 78 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 Sullivan & Cromwell LLP is a global law firm with the preeminent financial institutions practice, focusing on M&A, finance and capital raising, complex regulatory issues, corporate governance, legislative developments, significant litigation and enforcement matters, corporate investigations and tax matters. Founded in 1879, Sullivan & Cromwell LLP has approximately 800 lawyers on four continents. www.sullcrom.com new york . washington , d . c . . los angeles . palo alto london . paris . frankfurt tokyo . hong kong . beijing . melbourne . sydney do not include the volatility-leverage connection, the Structural GARCH provides a framework for empirical modeling of asset volatility, equity volatility, and leverage. The Structural GARCH model for systemic risk measurement provides earlier signals of financial firm distress. Additionally, the authors define a new measure they call “precautionary capital,” which determines how much equity firms need to add today in order to ensure an arbitrary level of confidence that the firm will not go bankrupt in a future crisis. Engle, Robert and Emil Siriwardane (2014), “Structural GARCH: The Volatility-Leverage Connection” OFR Working Paper, 14-07, (October). Impact of Systemic Risk on Bank Failure. The authors find that: (i) the impact from systemic risk on bank failure appears to be strong over the one-year forecast horizon but weakens over the one-quarter horizon; (ii) firms with higher capital ratios are more affected by systemic risk, suggesting that the buffer provided by higher capital ratios is weakened during the period when systemic risk is high; (iii) small banks are equally affected by systemic risk; and (iv) local housing market conditions are a major determinant of bank failure. Wu, Deming and Xinlei Zhao (2014), “Systemic Risk and Bank Failure,” mimeo, Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, (August). Interchange Fees Interchange Fee Income Significantly Reduced for Banks. The authors find that Regulation II reduced income at large banks by nearly $14 billion a year or more than 5% of core total noninterest income. Furthermore, in response to the decreased revenue for card transactions banks increased their deposit fees which offset roughly 30% of the lost interchange income. Kay, Benjamin Mark Manuszak and Cindy Vojtech (2014), “Bank Profitability and Debit Card Interchange Regulation: Bank Responses to the Durbin Amendment,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series, Divisions 80 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs, Federal Reserve Board. Bank Structure Ring Fencing Foreign Affiliate Increases Stress on Parent Bank. The authors find a significant positive correlation between parent banks’ and their foreign subsidiaries’ default risk. This risk is lower for subsidiaries operating in countries that impose higher capital, reserve, provisioning, and disclosure requirements and tougher restrictions on bank activities. The authors note that although tighter host banking regulations seem to help insulate foreign subsidiaries from changes in the default risk of parent banks during crises, ring fencing measures taken by authorities in one country could increase stress on the banking group’s legal entities in other jurisdictions or for the banking group as a whole. Furthermore, ring fencing may create inefficiencies in the allocation of capital and liquidity within multinational bank groups. Anginer, Deniz, Eugenio Cerutti and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria (2014), “Foreign Bank Subsidiaries’ Default Risk During the Global Crisis,” World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper, 7053, (October). Capital Leverage Based Capital Constraint Superior When Monitoring Loan Portfolios. The paper investigates whether a bank faced with a leverage based capital constraint monitors its loans better than a bank under a risk-based capital constraint. It finds that the biggest banks will monitor their portfolios when faced with leverage-based capital constraints, and will not monitor their portfolios when faced with risk-based capital constraints. According to the report, it appears that leverage ratios have better pre-crisis predictability than risk based approaches. Balasubramanyan, Lakshmi (2014), “Differential Capital Requirements: Leverage Ratio versus Risk-Based SEI is proud to support The Clearing House Annual Conference seic.com/institutional ©2 014 S EI Capital Ratio from a Monitoring Perspective,” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper, 14-15, (October). More Capital Would Improve Resilience. The authors use data on UK banks’ minimum capital requirements to study the interaction of monetary policy and regulatoryimposed capital requirements. They find that capital requirements are a more powerful tool for achieving financial stability objectives related to loan supply than monetary policy and therefore argue that “minimum capital requirement changes might offer a more potent tool for improving the resilience of the financial system, by moderating bank lending, over the cycle.” Aiyar, Shhekhar, Charles Calomiris and Tomasz Wieladek (2014), “How does credit supply respond to monetary policy and bank minimum capital requirements?” Bank of England Working Paper, 508, (September). Stress Testing What Governs Recovery from Banking Crises? The authors find that banks that are tougher on extending credit to their riskiest customers tend to recover from sudden declines in profitability. Based on this finding, the authors propose that regulators adjust bank stress tests to keep track of which customers’ loans would go bad during a crisis, and to consider how readily a bank can manage these problems. They conclude that indiscriminant reductions in lending seem to be less important than managing the risk associated with the riskiest borrowers. Kashyap, Anil and Emilia Bonaccorsi di Patti (2014), “Which Banks Recover from Large Adverse Shocks?” Chicago Booth Research Paper, 14-34, (September). Bank Balance Sheets Non-Traditional Bank Income Is Associated with Higher Bank Profitability. The authors examine how 82 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 banks’ non-traditional activities affect profitability and risk taking. Using data from bank Call Reports, they examine whether a higher ratio of non-interest income (i.e., bank’s non-core activities) to interest income (i.e., bank’s core deposit-taking and lending activities) is linked to higher bank profitability and risk taking. The authors find that a higher fraction of non-interest to interest income is associated with higher profitability, and that the higher profitability does not result from higher risk taking. Furthermore, the they find that banks which generate a higher fraction of their income from non-traditional business have a lower probability of bank insolvency. Saunders, Anthony, Markus Schmid and Ingo Walter (2014), “Non-Interest Income and Bank Performance: Is Banks’ Increased Reliance on Non-Interest Income Bade?” mimeo, New York University, University of St. Gallen, (October). CCPs Assessing the ‘Cover 2’ Standard for CCP Regulation. The authors address the safety and soundness of CCPs, specifically looking at the regulatory standard for CCPs, called ‘cover 2’, which states that systemically important clearing houses must have sufficient financial resources to ‘cover’, or be robust under the failure of, their two largest members in extreme circumstances. They argue that this is an unusual standard because it does not take into account the number of members a CCP has and question the prudency of the ‘cover 2’ standard for different sizes of CCP. The authors determine that CCPs meeting the ‘cover 2’ standard are not highly risky assuming that tail risks are not distributed uniformly amongst CCP members. However, the findings support the conclusion that CCPs and their supervisors should monitor this distribution as central clearing evolves. Murphy, David and Paul Nahai-Williamson (2014), “Dear Prudence, won’t you come out to play? Approaches to the analysis of central counterparty default fund adequacy,” Bank of England, Financial Stability Paper, 30, (October). I expec¶ my bank §o: Know my business, not just my balance. Some business owners expect more than just an account. They expect their bank to understand their business. When it’s time, come to Comerica. And discover why we’re the leading bank for business,* with more awards for excellence** than any other bank. RAISE YOUR EXPECTATIONS. ® Business Wealth Management Personal comerica.com MEMBER FDIC. EQUAL OPPORTUNITY LENDER. *Based on commercial and industrial loans as a percentage of total assets. Data provided by Thomson Reuters Bank Insight, June 2014. **Greenwich Associates is a leading worldwide strategic consulting and research firm specializing in financial services. For Middle Market, the Greenwich Awards are based on nearly 14,000 market research interviews with U.S. companies with sales revenues of $10 million-$500 million, and honorees were recognized by their customers as providing superior quality of products, service and coverage. Of more than 750 U.S. banks evaluated, Comerica ranked within the top 5 percent of banks with “distinctive quality” and “performing at a differentiated level relative to peers.” For Small Business, the Greenwich Awards are based on more than 17,000 market research interviews with U.S. companies with annual revenues of $1 million-$10 million, and honorees were recognized by their customers as providing superior quality of products, service and coverage. Of more than 750 U.S. banks evaluated, Comerica ranked within the top 6 percent of small business banks with “distinctive quality” and “performing at a differentiated level relative to peers.” CBP-4177 10/14 Featured Moments TCH Annual Fall Leadership Dinner. The Clearing House held its Annual Fall Leadership Dinner in September at the St. Regis Hotel in Washington, D.C. to honor the contributions and efforts of all TCH Owner Banks. The University of Chicago’s Randy Kroszner delivered keynote remarks on monetary policy and macroprudential regulation. Union Bank’s CEO, Masashi Oka, greets Bank of America’s Brian Moynihan at a reception before the dinner. JPMorgan Chase’s Stephen Cutler and KeyCorp’s Paul Harris. 84 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 BB&T’s Kelly King and the Financial Services Forum’s Rob Nichols. Sullivan & Cromwell’s H. Rodgin Cohen, the Brookings Institution’s Doug Elliott, and Comerica’s Ralph Babb pose for a photo at the pre-dinner reception. Fifth Third Bank’s Kevin Kabat enjoys a conversation at the pre-dinner reception. U.S. Bank’s Richard Davis introduces the University of Chicago’s Randy Kroszner before his keynote remarks. JPMorgan Chase’s Sandra O’Connor, Paul Saltzman of The Clearing House, and Pat Parkinson and Barbara Rehm of Promontory on the St. Regis patio. Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 85 In the Vault Ceremonial Trowel This ceremonial trowel was used to lay the cornerstone of TCH’s Cedar Street building in 1894. TCH’s home until 1963, the Cedar Street building contained a collection of now rare coins minted in 1896 – the year of the building’s dedication. 86 Banking Perspective Quarter 4 2014 © 2014 Citigroup Inc. Citi and Citi with Arc Design are registered service marks of Citigroup Inc. THE WORLD’S CITI. IT’S WHEREVER YOU ARE. It isn’t New York or London or Beijing. It’s not Lagos or São Paulo or Dubai. Today, it’s wherever you are. Where you bring your ideas, drive, passion and a hope that someone will believe in you. What if a bank made that its job? Where people come together to create or build something, we’re there to help make it real. For over 200 years. Around the world. citi.com/progress Celebrating more than 160 years of leadership, collaboration and innovation. For more than 160 years, The Clearing House and its Owner Banks have together addressed the most critical issues facing the banking industry and created innovative solutions to common problems. And our accomplishments are many—from helping shape banking policy and regulation to the creation and operation of safe and sound payment systems. The legacy of working together is a framework that will provide the banking industry with great new possibilities and success in the future. Bank of America Bank of the West Barclays BB&T BNY Mellon Capital One Citi Citizens Comerica Deutsche Bank Fifth Third HSBC JPMorgan Chase KeyBank M&T PNC Santander State Street SunTrust TD Bank UBS Union Bank U.S. Bank Wells Fargo