The Electoral System and Multi-Partyism in Kenya - Hanns
Transcription
The Electoral System and Multi-Partyism in Kenya - Hanns
The Electoral System and Multi-Partyism in Kenya African Research and Resource Forum (ARRF) Hanns Seidel Foundation The Electoral System and Multi-Partyism in Kenya African Research and Resource Forum (ARRF) Hanns Seidel Foundation ISBN 9966 - 7062 - 4 - 0 copyright 2007 Contents 1.0. The Case for Electoral System Reform in Kenya By Michael Chege 1 1.1 Introduction 1 1.2 Counting Progress 2 1.3 Half Century of Electoral Politics in Kenya 6 1.4 Generic Electoral System Types and their relevance to Kenya 17 1.5 Comparing Electoral Reforms and Consolidation of Democracy in Africa 21 1.6 A mixed Electoral System for Kenya 26 1.7 Conclusion 32 2.0 The Kenyan Electoral System By ECK Vice Chairman, Mr. Gabriel Mukele 2.1 Introduction 35 35 2.2 History of the Kenyan Electoral Process 36 2.3 The electoral Commission Set up 38 2.4 The Electoral law of Kenya 39 2.5 The 2002 General Elections 46 2.6 Conclusion 48 3.0. The Electoral System and Mullti-partyism in Kenya By Njeeri Kabeberi 49 3.1. The Electoral System 49 3.2. Multi-Party politics in Kenya 52 Foreword Kenya, like many modern states of the world practices representative democracy in which the sovereignty of the people is exercised through their elected representatives. Since a representative democracy assigns significant powers to the elected leaders, there are legitimate concerns about how the leaders are chosen, the expanse of their jurisdiction, as well as their scope of influence. This is why the electoral system is an extremely important aspect of any democratic country. Simply put, it is the electoral system that dictates who represents how many people and in what area or jurisdiction. An electoral system is essentially the method by which the votes of the electorate are translated into seats in the national legislative body. The two most popular electoral systems in the world today are the Single Member District (SMD) and the various forms of Proportional Representation (PR). We also have the two-round run off system of single member districts practiced mostly in the Francophone African Countries. Kenya is currently under the SMD, also called the First Past The Post (FPTP) system, which is sometimes criticised for creating electoral districts (constituencies, as they are called in Kenya) of unequal populations thus leading to disproportionate regional representation at the national assembly. Another common criticism of the SMD system is that it makes it possible for political parties to have a greater proportion of the seats in parliament than their proportion of the vote. So that it is possible for a party that enjoys say a 50% majority of the total vote to have less than a 50% majority in parliament. This is however not to suggest that other systems are not without shortcomings. Under Proportionate Representation (PR) for instance, it is difficult for the electorate to hold individual legislators accountable because voters may choose between alternative lists of many candidates who represent different political parties without specific districts. This poses a unique problem in a context like Kenya where legislators play a direct role in the development of their constituencies. iv The Electoral Commission of Kenya The challenge, therefore, is to discuss possible models of electoral system that will address the problem of disproportionate representation while at the same time avoiding the lack of accountability in the PR system. Hanns Seidel Foundation cannot purport to have specific solutions to the challenges facing the electoral system in Kenya today. It is neither in our interest nor within our mandate to suggest specific solutions. However, Hanns Seidel Foundation seeks to facilitate an open discussion about issues relevant to the democratic development of Kenya. This publication summarises the presentations and deliberations generated at a workshop on the electoral system of Kenya jointly organised by the African Research and Resource Forum (ARRF) and the Hanns Seidel Foundation. This publication is intended to encourage the wider sharing of knowledge and information, among the many individuals and institutions interested in the subject. We hope that this publication will advance the discourse on the subject, and prompt action aimed at the improvement of Kenya’s electoral system to further strengthen the country’s democratisation. The content and views contained in this publication reflect the opinion of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of Hanns Seidel Foundation. Dr. Wolf Krug Resident Representative Hanns Seidel Foundation The Electoral Commission of Kenya v vi The Electoral Commission of Kenya 1.0 The Case for Electoral System Reform in Kenya Michael Chege 1.1 Introduction W hatever yardstick one uses, Kenya has made remarkable progress towards democratic governance and the respect of civil liberties compared to the dark days of the Kenya African National Union (KANU) regime prior to 2003. This is also the case when Kenya’s development is compared to most of her neighbours. There, however, is no reason for complacency. That progress has brought major governance flaws into sharp focus, notably the capacity to deal with new and old corruption, as well as the monumental political challenges that have brought many African states to their knees: management of ethnic demands (including regional autonomy), and the mounting of national elections that bear the stamp of legitimacy. As Kenya heads to the December 2007 elections, the debate on both issues has sprung to the fore. According to the most recent theories of government, and given an ethnically pluralistic society like Kenya, some of the proposals already on the table - especially those based on majority decision rules (like referendums), uniform devolution, and run-off elections - could worsen a grave political situation. Consensual democracy, grand coalitions, inclusive power-sharing, and proportional representation are infinitely better-suited. This paper examines the contribution which one of these set of reforms electoral change towards a “Mixed” system combining single constituency with a plurality victory (as at present), and Proportional Representation that caters for currently unrepresented or under-represented groups. To have the desired effect in responding to ethnic demands going back to half a century, these changes need to be accompanied by a profound multiple devolution system that allows regions or districts to opt for or against government from the centre on key contentious issues that have remained unresolved since the 1960s. The Electoral Commission of Kenya Either way, its recommendations point towards a plurality of solutions, rather than the uniformity and centralisation that have plagued both Kenya and other African states since independence in the 1960s. 1.2 Counting Progress: Democratic Governance in Kenya since 2002 G oing by most public opinion polls conducted in Kenya since the December 2002, when KANU lost power for the first time in 40 years, a vast majority of Kenyans indicate that they enjoy a greater scope of political freedom than at any other time except the brief period immediately after independence in 1963. According to the latest polls, only 7 per cent of Kenyans surveyed in August 2006 state that Kenya is not a democracy, compared to 76 per cent who think it is now a democracy to a “full” extent (17 per cent), or a democracy experiencing “minor” or “serious” problems (59 per cent). According to the national household survey conducted under the African Peer Review Mechanism (APRM) of New Partnership of Africa’s Development (NEPAD) in August 2005, Kenyans gave the highest approval ratings to the prevalence of freedoms of worship, speech, travel, association and assembly. This was confirmed by NEPAD’s external review panel of experts in October 2005. The panel found that “democratic space had increased remarkably during the previous two years….Political and civil rights are exercised with considerable degree of freedom and few restrictions. The civil society movement in Kenya engages the Government in a robust and fruitful manner…In effect Kenya’s civil society movement continues expansion of the political space”. All this is in line with what other independent observers of trends in democratisation in Africa have concluded. Using a composite index of civil and political freedoms, Freedom House in New York rates over 190 countries annually on a scale of 1-2.5 (“free), 3-5 (“partly free”), to 5.5-7 (“not free”). Kenya’s rating fell from a tyrannical level of 6.5 in 1996 to 3 in 2006. . Westminster Foundation for Democracy, “Using Multiparty Democracy in Kenya”, Nairobi, August 2006, p. 12. 17 per cent were not sure or refused to answer. . Kenya NEPAD Secretariat, “Kenya National Self-Assessment Report of the APRM”, Nairobi: Ministry of Planning and National Development, 2005. . NEPAD, “APRM Country Review Report of the Republic of Kenya”, Midrand, South Africa: APRM Secretariat, 2006. p.80 The Electoral Commission of Kenya This places her among the 13 freest countries in Africa, much better than any of her neighbours—Tanzania (3.5), Uganda (4.5), and Ethiopia (5.0). Kenya is classified as the only “electoral democracy” in eastern Africa. Credit for that dramatic change for the better goes to ordinary citizens, committed professionals, and organised groups that confronted tyrannical rule in all its manifestations from the 1960s to the darkest days in the 1990s, and often paid a high price for it. Many non-Kenyans and foreign institutions made significant contributions to that remarkable transition. The gains made need to be consolidated. As Kenyans celebrate democratic progress, it would be foolhardy to ignore the institutional deficiencies and governance challenges facing the country, whose profile has been brought to sharper focus by political openness in the wake of the transition. Some of these can be deduced from polls and careful political analysis of events (like elections and referendums) and stated aspirations of leaders and followers. The NEPAD external review cited the danger of ethnic animosities following the November 2005 constitutional referendum; economic inequalities between regions and between the rich and poor; impunity from corruption and abuse of office; gender inequality; and lack of a “transformative leadership”. In the polls, Kenyans continue to express distrust and discontent with their elected legislators and to insist that the Government should do more to rein in corruption by prosecuting past and present offenders. Though hugely satisfied with the reforms introduced in the education and health sectors - and to a lesser extent in prisons, agriculture and public transport - Kenyans are overwhelmingly dissatisfied with the lack of employment opportunities, insecurity, and low incomes despite the resumption of economic growth in the last four years. A democratic government embraces a continuous process of mutuallynegotiated political innovation to problems in the interest of higher social ideals binding society together. These include security (the ultimate reason for the state), safeguards against any violation of individual liberty, and access to the essentials in life that make freedom meaningful -human rights, adequate nutrition, health, education and shelter. Not surprisingly, contemporary political debate in Kenya now centres on some of these issues: constitutional reforms that The Electoral Commission of Kenya ensure more equitable representation (of ethnic groups and women), devolution of constitutional responsibilities to regions or districts, more equitable distribution of income and employment opportunities (often tied to devolution), reduction of executive power, more accountability of rulers, and wider representation in the electoral commission and public service. Kenya is a culturally-pluralistic society. It is characterised by sharp internal cleavages based on ethnic identity, language, region of origin, race, culture and religion. At the heart of the reform debate in Kenya lie two broad political sentiments: the desire for a more perfect democracy and the resolution of deep-seated ethnic claims and grievances. In addressing these problems, one constitutional innovation that could be a useful tool in responding to these challenges is electoral reform. Electoral systems define the manner in which the wishes of the voters are translated into voter representation in the legislature and decision-making in government. In all culturally-segmented societies, social group interests are expressed through the ballot. In the most successful of that lot, innovations in electoral systems have often been used to introduce national governance systems that meet the challenges posed by ethnic and regional differences that Kenya faces. This was the case in South Africa in the run-up to the 2004 elections that ended apartheid, Northern Ireland following the Good Friday agreement of 1998, Zimbabwe at independence in 1980, Mozambique in 1994, and Namibia at the pre-independence elections of 1989. In all these cases, the choice of the electoral system - the rules behind balloting, computation of winning candidates, party representation in the legislature according to votes received - was based on broad inclusiveness of groups that had previously been locked in conflict. To cultivate a sense of security at community level, the success of electoral reforms has been premised on complementary constitutional innovations. These include power-sharing, grand coalition government, minority veto, devolution and regional autonomy or fully-fledged federalism, quotas in top appointments and affirmative action for groups that cannot acquire representation in any other way. Apart from a fleeting recommendation (in the constitutional debates in 2001) for “mixed” electoral system - combining Proportional Representation (PR) with the The Electoral Commission of Kenya present first-past-the-post (FPTP) method - changes in Kenya’s election system have never occupied centre stage in country’s governance reform agenda. Two prominent scholars of government in Kenya have dealt with the issue of electoral reforms in the country, simulating what the outcomes would be under alternative voting systems. However, their findings and recommendations have not caught as much public attention as they deserve. Focusing on whether PR could have made a difference in party representation in the 1997 election, Ndegwa concluded it could not have, while Barkan demonstrated that more equitable constituency delimitation could have produced more representative in opposition to the KANU government in the 1990s. This paper takes it from where they left and hopes to advance the debate on electoral reform in Kenya at a time when the momentum for constitutional reform is again gaining strength. It begins with a summary of Kenya’s electoral history and the lessons learned from it and proceeds to an abbreviated survey of available options in electoral systems that the country might consider. Given the country’s ethnically-segmented voting pattern, a reality that need not be condemned outright, it comes out in favour of a “mixed” PR and FPTP system, complemented by reforms involving power-sharing, grand coalition governments, devolution and regional autonomy, and affirmative action for the smallest groups that have been previously been denied representation. In its most generic form, this is what Arend Lijphart refers to as consensus or “consociational” democracy; the form best suited to countries like Kenya. . Stephen N. Ndegwa, “The Relevance of Electoral Systems: A Simulation of the 1992 Kenyan Election”, Nairobi, Institute for Development Studies, University of Nairobi, 1997; Joel Barkan, Paul Densham, and Gerard Rushton, “Space Matters: Designing Better Electoral Systems for Emerging Democracies”, American Journal of Political Science, October, 2006. . Arend Lijphart, Democracy in Plural Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1977) The Electoral Commission of Kenya 1.3 Half a Century of Electoral Politics in Kenya, 1957-2007: Some Lessons of Experience E uropean settlers in the Kenya colony enjoyed universal franchise and elected representation in the colonial Legislative Council since 1920 when they were allocated 11 seats. This replaced nominations to the legislature by the Governor, which had been the practice since 1907. In 1920, electoral regulations were amended to permit the election of two Indian members, a Muslim and a Hindu. Between 1920 and 1960, communal (racial) seat allocations for Europeans, Asians and Arabs increased as the legislature grew but official members (civil servants) remained a majority in the colonial legislature until 1948. The first African nominated member of the Legislative Council, Eliud Mathu, took his seat in the council in 1944. He was joined by five others and this brought African representation to six out of 28 members by 1956. The Mau Mau rebellion in 1952 forced quick rethinking about African representation in the Kenyan government by the Colonial Office in London. This led to the first direct elections of African members to the Legislative Council on a highly restrictive franchise in 1957. But once the door was opened, it proved impossible to close. As McMillan’s “winds of change” swept the continent, it was just a matter of time before a majority African legislature was conceded. Under the Lyttelton Constitution of 1955, Walter Coutts - an administrator with long experience in the colony - was commissioned to prepare a formula for African representation in the Legislative Council through of direct election. Coutts’ recommendations provided for a highly restricted franchise under which African voters were required to meet at least three out of ten conditions on education, wealth, public or military service, business ownership, etc. - and demonstrated loyalty to the government. Voters were allocated multiple votes, no more than four, depending on the conditions they satisfied. The multiple ballots could be cast for the same or for alternate contestants. Candidates needed to meet voter and other conditions (language, education and income). For the Kikuyu, Embu and Meru, both voter and candidate needed a “loyalist certificate” demonstrating their disassociation with the Mau Mau movement. There were eight seats at stake, one from each province, the then Northern Frontier region having been excluded. The Electoral Commission of Kenya In March 1957, Africans in Kenya voted for the first time in history, albeit in a limited franchise. The first eight elected representatives in the Legislative Council, many of whom were to shape politics in independent Kenya, were: Tom J. Mboya (Nairobi); Jaramogi Oginga Odinga (Central Nyanza); Masinde Murilo (North Nyanza); Lawrence Oguda (South Nyanza); D.T. arap Moi (Rift Valley); Bernard Mate (Central Province); J.N.Muimi (Akamba); and Ronald Ngala (Coast). Once inside the legislature, the eight, under Mboya’s leadership, fought for an additional six African elected seats to bring Africans to parity with European legislators. This was conceded by the Lennox-Boyd Constitution of 1957 which allowed six additional African constituencies that were contested in 1958. This brought African representation in the Legislative Council to 14, although they were still a minority. The situation never changed until 1960. Over time, these elections have been interpreted differently. Following Bennet and Rosberg, Keith Kyle saw them as cutting edge of the rising tide of African nationalism that could not be contained by the official attempts to formulate a moderate “multi-racial” government. Indeed Kenya politics, after 1958, were dominated by demands for majority rule on the basis of universal adult franchise and the release of Jomo Kenyatta from prison. Others consider those elections as the beginning of the installation of a compliant African petitbourgeoisie, or some variation thereof, which could be trusted to manage the colonial economy in the future. Re-examining the 1957 election in Central Kenya, for instance, Daniel Branch considers the elections to have marked “the first triumph of the system” with the loyalists edging out Mau Mau adherents and their leaders. These explanations are not necessarily incompatible; being adopted into the system and pursuing a nationalist agenda can be done . For the most detailed account of these elections see G.F. Engholm, “African Elections in Kenya, March 1957”, in W.J.M. Mackenzie and Kenneth Robinson, eds., Five Elections in Africa (Oxford University Press, 1960). Of the eight, only Mboya commanded a genuinely strong intra-ethnic constituency, precisely because it was urban. . The 1958 cohort was also to remain dominant in post-independence Kenya politics, by dint of their regional following: J.J.M. Nyagah (Embu), Julius Gikonyo Kiano (Muranga and Kiambu); Taita Towett (Kipsigis); . Keith Kyle, The Politics of Independent Kenya, (New York, St. Martins Press, 1999), pp.75-86; George Bennett and Carl Rosberg, The Kenyatta Election, 1960-61 (London, Oxford University Press, 1961), pp.11-16. . Daniel Branch, “Loyalists, Mau Mau and Elections in Kenya”, Africa Today”, Vol.53, No.2, 2006. See also Colin Leys, Underdevelopment in Kenya: The Political Economy of Neo-Colonialism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975), pp.43-52. The Electoral Commission of Kenya simultaneously. As can be seen by the access to power of the African National Congress of South Africa (1994), Zimbabwe African National Union (1980), and South West African Peoples Organisation in Namibia (1990), nationalist parties and liberation movements that brought majority rule to Southern Africa changed the racial texture of political representation substantially while accommodating themselves to the economic and social institutions they inherited. It all depends on how one understood nationalism and the political mechanism that legislators and parties adopted in building it. In Kenyan elections, allegiance to ethnic homeland was to gradually compete with that to the wider national state. A mistake was made, and continues to be made, in considering both incompatible in the face of evidence that electoral and other formulas to accommodate both were available. Nation-wide African political parties in Kenya were banned in 1953 following the outbreak of the Mau Mau war. In 1955, the colonial government permitted the formation of political parties based on administrative districts - except in the Kikuyu, Embu and Meru region, which was still under the war regulations. This was a strategy to pre-empt the spread of violent politics outside Central Kenya. That, however, did not stop the Nairobi Peoples Convention Party, under Tom Mboya in Nairobi, from pursuing a national agenda, in line with the Ghana Peoples Convention Party. Most of the district parties were concerned with local issues such as better access to government services, employment, income opportunities, health and education. Within the colonial legislature, African members eventually coalesced around two loose informal groups: the Kenya Independence Movement (under Oginga Odinga, Gikonyo Kiano and Tom Mboya) keen to promote African majority rule under a unitary state; and a moderate multiracial Kenya National Group (including Masinde Murilo, Ronald Ngala, and Daniel arap Moi) which favoured a slower pace to majority rule and decentralised government as a safeguard for local ethnic interests, and against “dictatorship”. As Daniel arap Moi, then head of the Baringo District Independent Party, said in 1958, such a system was necessary “because tribalism will live for at least another 50 years”10 As David Anderson has shown, the fissure had already opened between advocates of a strong central authority 10. Quoted in Keith Kyle, Politics of the Independence of Kenya, p.77. The Electoral Commission of Kenya and those of a federalist (majimbo) state with substantive local autonomy for ethnic homelands that was to become a defining characteristic of intra-African politics in Kenya in the early 1960s, then again in the 1990s.11 In mid-1960 when nation-wide political parties were again allowed, the advocates of majimbo (regional federalism) coalesced under the Kenya African Democratic Union (KADU), while those of a strong central government with equal citizen rights regardless of ethnic or regional origin regrouped under the Kenya African National Union (KANU). Under the leadership of James Gichuru, Oginga Odinga, Tom Mboya (and Kenyatta after 1961), KANU drew its support primarily from Kikuyu and related communities in Central Kenya, Luo (in Nyanza and all urban areas), Kamba, Kisii, part of Luhya, Kisii and Taita. KADU appealed to the then predominantly pastoral communities (Kalenjin, Maasai, Samburu, Pokot), Mijikenda at the Coast, and part of the Luhya. This was out of suspicions of domination by the larger and more educated groups and fears over loss of traditional lands, particularly to the Kikuyu. And the problem lay not so much in the enduring tribal hostilities of the kind Moi imagined in 1958 - Kenyans for the most part actually got on well across ethnic lines, considering the chasms in culture and language. The problem lay in opportunistic exploitation of those differences by leaders keen to build an ethnic electoral base and institutional failure to adapt to ethnic interests as expressed in electoral and party politics before and after independence. The 1960, McCleod Constitution - in response to African demands in the Legislative Council and an attempt to bring closure to Mau Mau after the Hola massacre of 1959 - allowed an elected African majority in the Legislative Council for the first time. Though roundly condemned by most conservative European leaders, the electoral format envisaged for 1961 was a widely acceptable compromise that combined a universal franchise with an African elected majority (33 “open” seats out of 53), but also reserved 20 constituencies for candidates from racial minorities: ten for Europeans, eight for Asians (split between Muslims and non-Muslims), and two for the Arabs. Eligible voters of any race resident in the 20 “reserved” constituencies were allowed to vote 11. David M. Anderson, “Yours in the Struggle for Majimbo”, Journal of Contemporary History, Vol.40, No.3, 2005. The Electoral Commission of Kenya for any of the candidates, but the had to primary elections restricted to the racial minorities (Asian or Europeans) allocated the seat, to ensure the ballot represented genuine community choice, not a candidates without popular following in the racial groups but who could take the seats due to backing from African nationalist parties. Two issues dominated the 1961 elections. First, as Bennett and Rosberg observed, there was agitation for the release of Jomo Kenyatta (then in detention at Maralal), hence “the Kenyatta election”.12 Secondly, voting patterns for the first time clearly reflected wholesale ethnic preference for one party, rather than many parties with a following in one ethnic group. Bennett and Rosberg referred to this as the phenomenon of “one party tribes”. Thus KANU won a majority of the African seats (19 out of 33) to 11 of KADU. Three seats went to smaller ethnically-confined parties. Another factor that Bennett and Rosberg’s study glossed over was the impact of the first-past-the-post system. A number of high profile seats went to minority candidates as a result of two contestants often in the same party: Nakuru Town, Meru and North Nyanza. In addition, there was a discrepancy between the percentage of votes received by parties and the number of seats won. KANU took 67 per cent of the vote but only 57 of the “open” seats; this is the phenomenon of “electoral disproportionality”. Both phenomena were to be amplified as time went by. The pre-independence elections in 1963 pitted KADU against KANU once again, but this time with a difference. This time, special communal rolls were replaced by universal suffrage in 112 single-member constituencies in the House of Representatives, 38 Senate seats, and six regional assemblies. As Sanger and Nottingham demonstrated, KANU had by this time acquired superior organisational skills and funding from its pan-African connections. This is what KADU lacked and was becoming increasingly disorganised. It was unable to field candidates in all the 112 constituencies.13 The result was a KANU landslide. After the dust settled, it took 68 seats out of 112 (60 per cent) in the House of Representatives, derived from 67 per cent of the popular vote, and 20 of the 38 Senate seats. KADU took 32 seats in the 12. Bennett and Roberg, The Kenyatta Election, p.126. 13. Clyde Sanger and John Nottingham, “The Kenya General Election of 1963”, Journal of Modern African Studies, Vol.2, No.1, 1964 10 The Electoral Commission of Kenya House of Representatives, compared to eight of the African Peoples Party led by Paul Ngei, which soon crossed the floor to join KANU. But although KANU demonstrated more widespread national appeal than KADU, or than it had in 1961, the country was split at regional assembly level, and even within districts, on the basis of wholesale ethnic affiliation to one party. KADU took control of three regions (Rift Valley, Coast and Western) in comparison to three of KANU (Central, Eastern and Nyanza).14 Figure 1 below shows the regional distribution of party allegiance as of 1963. Fig 1: Regional Voting Patterns in 1963 14.No elections took place in North Eastern Province due to a popular boycott in favour of annexation of the region to Somalia. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 11 Genuine competitive multiparty elections returned to Kenya in 1992. As a result of the differences between radical and moderate factions within KANU, the country was thrust into the “Little General Election” of 1966 that pitted the ruling party against the Kenya Peoples Union (KPU) in 18 constituencies.15 Between the election and its proscription in 1969, KPU faced official harassment and coercive restrictions that ultimately reduced the base of its support to Luo-Nyanza. As in most of post-independence Africa, competitive party politics gave way to onepart states soon after independence. In Kenya the process was gradual and, by most authoritative accounts, single party rule in 1969 tolerated considerable internal competition at election time until 1988. In the four intervening elections - those of 1969, 1974, 1979, and 1983 - between 40 per cent (1983) and 65 per cent (1969) of the incumbents lost their seats. In a survey conducted in 1974, Barkan reported that most voters rated their MPs on how well they conveyed their views to the government and their capacity to obtain projects and benefits for the constituency, confirming some of the conclusion arrived at by Leys and Hyden about the 1969 election.16 This was confirmed for subsequent elections under one-party rule by Throup and Hornsby.17 But as these authors demonstrate, presidential authoritarianism and rigging were already creeping in, culminating in the farcical “queuing” of voters behind candidates in 1988. At this time, discontent with the authoritarian and corrupt ways of the KANU regime was building up, heading for a showdown with the opposition in 1990. The 1992 general elections, the result of the protracted campaign for multiparty elections in the previous two years, have attracted consider analysis. The most detailed is the volume by Throup and Hornsby, arguably the most detailed study of a national election in Africa then.18 The regime’s opponents had split three ways, and so in an election marred by officially-sanctioned ethnic violence, corruption 15. Cherry Gertzel, The Politics of Independent Kenya (Nairobi: East African Publishing House, 1970), pp??; and Susan Mueller, “Government and Opposition in Kenya”, Journal of Modern African Studies, Vol. 22, No. No.3, 1984. 16.Joel Barkan,“Legislators, Elections, Political Linkage”, in Joel Barkan and John Okumu, eds., Politics and Public Policy in Kenya and Tanzania (New York: Praeger, 1979); Goran Hyden and Colin Leys, Elections and Politics in Single Party Systems: The Case of Kenya and Tanzania”, British Journal of Political Science, Vol.2, No 4, 1972. 17.David Throup, “Elections and Political Legitimacy in Kenya”, Africa, Vol.63, No.3, 1993; Charles Hornsby and David Throup, “Elections and Political Change in Kenya”, Journal of Commonwealth and Comparative Politics, Vol. 32, No, 2, 1992. 18. David Throup and Charles Hornsby, Multiparty Politics in Kenya (Oxford: James Currey, 1998). 12 The Electoral Commission of Kenya and intimidation, “KANU won a decisive victory based on a vote of less than one third of the country. This was partly as a result of the incompetence of the opposition, partly because of their willingness to bribe, threaten and cheat their way to victory, and partly because the Government continued to represent the interests of key less developed communities in the country, whose loyalty they were able to retain.”19 In the parliamentary poll, KANU won 53 per cent of the seats with only 30 per cent of the vote. This was courtesy of constituency delimitation that favoured the less-populated KANU-supporting areas (previously supportive of KADU) and the impact of first-past-the-post system in an election with many parties. Cowen and Kanyinga say by this time, it was safe to conclude that KADU had resurrected itself in the guise of KANU, while communities supportive of KANU in 1963 had split their votes into the three opposition parties: Ford-Kenya, Ford-Asili, and the Democratic Party. Figure 2 reflects the regional distribution of party support, which also bears this out.20 Figure 2: Regional Distribution of Party Support, 1992 19. Throup and Hornsby, Multiparty Politics in Kenya..p.526. 20. Michael Cowen and Karuti Kanyinga,“The 1997 Elections in Kenya: The Politics of Community and Locality”, in Michael Cowen and Liisa Laakso (eds.,) Multi-party Elections in Africa (Oxford, James Currey, 2002), p.132. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 13 The 1997 elections largely followed the contours of the 1992 elections although there were some notable exceptions. Although Moi took a slightly higher plurality in the presidential poll (40 per cent), his KANU party won only 51 per cent of the parliamentary seats (108 out of 210). This made his government vulnerable to defeat via a motion of no-confidence, should it lose the support of a few MPs. Indeed as Grignon, Mazrui, and Rutten point out, the election was actually won by the combined opposition. Three seats - Westlands, Changamwe, and Kitui West—were won by KANU “out of the count” by ballotstuffing.21 This made it necessary for KANU to bring the National Development Party (NDP) of Raila Odinga (with its 21 seats) into an informal alliance with the Government even though NDP was to sit in the Opposition benches. Academic and popular explanations of the two elections see Kenyan politics in highly pessimistic terms. This position is largely justified by the continuity of a tyrannical government despite the repeated elections, the continued split of the Opposition on basis of self-interest of party leaders, a culture of self-destructive ethnic inclusiveness among the voters, an amoral political leadership in all parties, and, above all, susceptibility of the public to political violence, bribery and corruption. The 1997 election has been covered in great detail and by more authors than that of 1992.22 This is true whether one is referring to national presidential elections, patterns of voting in ethnic homelands, urban areas or key constituencies. The greatest strength of this literature, and that of the databanks and analysis provided by the Institute for Education in Democracy and similar institutions, is its empirical contribution. It has given Kenya possibly the most detailed data on elections electoral behaviour at 21. Francois Grignon, Alamin Mazrui and Marcel Rutten, “Conclusion”, in Rutten, Mazrui and Grignon, Out of the Count: The 1997 General Elections and Prospects for Democracy in Kenya (Kampala: Fountain Publishers, 2001), p.594. 22. See the essays in Marcel Rutten, Al Amin Mazrui, and Francois Grignon, (eds.,) Out of the Count:The 1997 Elections and the Prospects for Democracy in Kenya (Kampala: Fountain Publishers, 2001; Ludeki Chweya, (ed.,), Electoral Politics in Kenya (Nairobi: Claripress, 2002); Smokin Wanjala, S. Kichamu Akivaga, and Kivutatha Kibwana, (eds.,) Yearning for Democrcay: Kenya at the Dawn of a New Century (Nairobi: Claripress, 2002). Also consult A. Tostensen, B.A. Andreassen, and K. Tronvoll, Kenya’s Hobbled Democracy Revisited: The 1997 General Elections in Retrospect and Prospects (Oslo: Norwegian Institute of Human Rights, University of Oslo, 1998). Rigging and state-engineered violence as an electoral strategy is dealt with by J.Klopp, “Ethnic Clashes and Winning Elections in Kenya”, Canadian Journal of African Studies, 2001; Rok Ajulu, “Kenya’s Democratic Experiment”, Review of African Political Economy, 1998; and Stephen Brown, “Quiet Diplomacy and Recurring Ethnic Clashes in Kenya”, in Chandra Sriram and Karen Wermester, (eds.,), From Promise to Practice: Strengthening UN Capacity for Prevention of Violent Conflict (Boulder, CO: Lynne Reinner, 2003). 14 The Electoral Commission of Kenya national and constituency level in Africa. It has also documented the systemic weaknesses inherent in Kenya politics and society, which made it possible for an authoritarian government presiding over catastrophic economic conditions to hang onto power for so long. But it has not engaged theories of governance reform directly relevant to the intractable political problems that it highlights, thereby pointing out some tested remedies in similar circumstances. It has often taken recourse in a wholesale moral and cultural regeneration agenda that is also deemed a long shot. For that reason, it is saturated by an all-pervading pessimism that could not have anticipated the events of 2002 and the qualified positive changes that we have identified. Part of the literature considered successful reforms nearimpossible given the perverse and corrupted political culture, ultimately based on endless “tribal” calculations, rather than national interest. Looking at the situation in 1997, for instance, Fox judged the future of multiparty politics in Kenya bleak.23 To Throup and Hornsby, even a participatory Kenyatta-era one party state would have been preferable to the “the primacy of ethnicity over ideology…communal solidarity and internal divisions…and lack of political principle within the Kenyan elite” that characterised the 1992 elections.24 To Chweya, electoral democracy in Africa of the 1990s “was on the verge of failure” because it was Western implant on African cultural and political soil that had failed to blend traditional and post-colonial traditions.25 More importantly, Walter Oyugi saw a law of ethnic (“tribal”) determinism at play in Kenya politics going back to the 1963 elections, about which Kenyans seemed to be in perpetual denial.26 To make democratic progress, this tradition and factors that produce it - like inequalities in resource distribution by the State - needed to be “tamed” but it was not made clear by whom and how. 23. Ron Fox, “Bleak Future for Multiparty Politics in Kenya”, Journal of Modern African Studies, Vol.43, No.3, 1998. 24.Throup and Hornsby, Multiparty Politics in Kenya, p.590-91. 25. Chweya, “Western Modernity, African Idigenem and Political Order: Interrogating the Liberal Democratic Orthodoxy”, in Chweya, Electoral Politics in Kenya, p.26. 26. Walter O. Oyugi, “Ethnic Relations and the Democratisation Process in Kenya, 1990-1997”, in Walter O. Oyugi, ed., Ethnicity and Democratisation in Africa (Dakar, Codesria Books, ???); and “Ethnicity in the Electoral Process: The 1992 General Elections in Kenya”, African Journal of Political Science, Vol.2, No.1, 1997. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 15 This is where institutional innovation through electoral and complementary constitutional reforms comes in. To start with, the most respected findings on the problem in Africa demonstrates that far from being a concretely-fixed and predictable quantity, ethnic identities are forever in flux depending on the situation and the issues at stake, making unitary tribes “an illusion”.27 Like in other parts of the world, the motivation and goals behind ethnic mobilisation are fabricated by “cultural entrepreneurs” not always with malicious intent. Such movements can be politically constructive even benign, while in other circumstances it can be a lethal weapon aimed at one group - as demonstrated by the Rwanda genocide in 1994, and the tribal clashes in Kenya in the 1990s. At every competitive election since 1960, negative ethnic mobilisation has been called in to buffet the voter base, subjecting cultural “outsiders” to violence. In the hands of reckless leaders, friend and foe are defined by convenience, which is why some of the recent studies on electoral politics in Kenya reveal ethnic political loyalties over time. Since “cultural pluralism” (to give it the right term), is a defining characteristic of Kenya society, it would be impossible to banish any appeal to it at election time without eliminating free speech and freedom of association altogether. The challenge lies in tolerating it, while snuffing out its lethal dimension. This is the dilemma that James Madison dealt with in Federalist Paper Number 10. Writing about the potential and danger of “faction” in a democracy, he concluded that rather than seek to extinguish it (and with it freedom), it is better to accord it toleration in a republic enjoying a wider “size and variety” of political institutions, not sameness of opinion. It sounds contradictory as do most valuable ideas from the Age of Reason (including Adam Smith’s derivation of greater public good from toleration of private pursuits) but it is a more realistic solution to Kenya’s problems than idealistic appeals to a uniform nationalism. Equal political rights must then be accorded to self-defined constituent communities as much as to individuals, as long as this is does not violate the rights of others. That is best done through a culture of tolerance and accommodation, powersharing, devolution (and federalism in particular), and electoral systems that widen representation, in “constant consociational bargaining”.28 One thing is for 27. See for one Crawford Young, The Politics of Cultural Pluralism, (Madsion, WI.: University of Wisconsin Press, 1976). Pp.34-65. 28. Young, Politics of Cultural Pluralism, p.527. 16 The Electoral Commission of Kenya sure, policies and electoral systems that contain “winner-take-all” and “majority always prevails” as ruling principles are ill-suited to competitive culturally pluralistic societies like Kenya. Political scientists and Kenyan election observers may be right in blaming the country’s “tribalistic” and opportunistic politicians, and their unquestioning ethnic followers, but a first-past-the-post system electoral system in a highly centralised State such as Kenya, is probably an even greater culprit. That is why the electoral system and some parallel constitutional reforms deserve a closer look. In this respect, the electoral and institutional framework most suitable for Kenya would be similar to that of post-apartheid South Africa, India, Switzerland, Austria and Belgium, rather than the UK or France - which have dominated the electoral models operating in their former African colonies. 1.4 Generic Electoral System Types and their Relevance to Kenya I n a 2005 study entitled Electoral System Design, by the International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance (IDEA), the authors commence their analysis by stating that “the choice of electoral systems is one of the most important institutional decisions for any democracy. In almost all cases, the choice of a particular electoral system has a profound effect on the future political life of the country concerned”.29 This statement is borne out by historical observations of democratic governance in action, and the role that electoral systems play in the process. In one of the most notable scholarly studies on the subject many years ago, Douglas Rae observed that different electoral systems affect the nature of party systems that emerged in a country, and the degree to which voters’ wishes in representation are reflected in the legislature and ultimately the government.30 Electoral systems could help engineer national politics. At the same time, Rae noted that all electoral systems have some effects in common: they seldom produce a legislature representation that fully accords with the proportions of votes cast for each party; they lead to under-representation of smaller parties in parliament; and they tend to “manufacture” majorities in legislatures that do not accord to the voter preferences at election time. In addition, studies on electoral systems indicate that having selected one pattern of voting and deciding on 29. Andrew Reynolds, Ben Reilly and Andrew Ellis, Electoral Systems Design: The New International IDEA (Stockholm, International IDEA, 2005) p.1 30. Douglas W. Rae, The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws (New Haven, Yale University Press, 1967) The Electoral Commission of Kenya 17 winners, countries find it extremely hard to switch to another system. This, as we shall see, is also true of African states. Electoral systems fall under two large families: (i) the “Plurality and Majority” cluster of rules under which winners are decided on the basis of which candidate among many contestants in a single member constituency receives the most votes (a plurality), or a majority (at least 50 per cent) of the total valid ballots cast; (ii) “Proportional Representation” (PR) which attempts to make the proportion of the votes cast for parties as close as possible to their representation in the legislature. There is a third cluster of electoral systems, which is usually referred to as “Mixed”. It combines characteristics of the two main ones. In practice, democratic countries increasingly reflect diversity between plurality/majority systems, PR, and mixed systems in legislative elections. This diversity is also marked in presidential and local government elections. Table I below summarises the three families of electoral systems, against examples of the most distinguished country practitioners as of 2005. Table I Main Categories of Electoral Systems 18 Family Sub-sets Examples Plurality/Majority : First-Past-the-Post : Two-Round System : Alternative Vote : Block Vote Britain France Australia Mauritius Proportion/ Representation : List PR : Single Transferable Vote South Africa Ireland Mixed : Parallel Plurality/PR : Mixed-Member PR Japan Germany The Electoral Commission of Kenya 1.4.1 Plurality and Majority Systems The most distinguishing characteristic of the British and US “first-past-the-post” (FPTP) system is the single-member constituency in which winning candidates are those who receive most of the votes, but not necessarily the majority. FPTP has the attraction of simplicity, strong accountability of legislators to a geographically-defined constituency, and a tendency to strengthen the twoparty system. It is however criticised for short-changing the smaller parties in parliamentary representation and for inadequate representation of women. In countries like France, the two-round system requires run offs among leading candidates in cases where none of them receives an outright majority the first time. In the run-offs the weakest candidates are excluded and a plurality can be used to declare a winner. African countries have largely taken the cue from Britain or France, adopting either FPTP or run-offs. In yet another variant of majoritanian voting systems, under the Alternative Vote (as in Australia) voters are required to indicate their preference for candidates in descending order (from first, second, third to the last). The outright winning candidates are those who receive an absolute majority in the first round. Should no candidate achieve that, the candidate with the lowest amount of numberone preferences is then dropped, and his or her votes then distributed to the candidates shown as the second choice in his or her ballots, a redistribution process that continues until an overall winner with a majority is identified. The alternative vote has been applied in Ireland’s presidential elections, but not in any African state so far. Block vote is another but less popular subset of the plurality/majority electoral systems. Voters in multi-member constituencies choose between parties, each of which fronts an agreed number of candidates. As under FPTP, the party with the most votes takes all the districts seats. This system has been applied in Mauritius, Singapore, Chad, Senegal and Cameroon. 1.4.2 Proportional Representation Under Proportional Representation family, the most common subset is “List PR”. There are some differences within List PR but it has fundamental characteristics. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 19 The contesting political parties nominate lists of candidates in order of priority for each (multi-member) district. Constituency ballots are then cast for parties and the seats allocated parties in proportion to the votes that they receive out of the total. South Africa has used this system since 1994, and it is a living example of how user-friendly List PR can be for deeply fragment societies, when combined with matching constitutional reforms under good leadership. An increasing number of African states have opted for List PR since the 1980s, making it one of the most popular electoral systems in the region. Advocates of PR defend it not just on the basis of proportional representation of voter wishes, but also on the basis of opening up access to minority parties, ethnic inclusiveness, and provision of more seats to women. This, as we have seen, is of special concern to democracies in Africa. PR is, however, criticised for producing coalition governments of convenience. They tend to be unstable and are prone to ransom behaviour by extremist parties at either left or right. In addition, legislators cannot be held strictly accountable to constituency development as under FPTP. Under the Single Transferable Vote (STV) of the PR family, voters rank candidates -rather than parties as in List PR -in multi-member constituencies, in a pattern akin to the Alternative Vote (AV) System. However, the formula for determining the winning candidates differs significantly from the majority-based AV pattern. Computation involves both re-arranging votes of the top and the lowest voterecipients. First, a quota of votes out of the total that each winning candidate should have is determined; usually as percentage share of total ballots cast, divided by the number of seats in the district. For outright winners, any surplus ballots above the quota are then allocated to candidates listed as the second preference. Next, the weakest candidates are eliminated and their votes distributed to the second voter preference. The process continues until all qualified candidates meet the quota threshold. STV is praised for meeting both party and candidate preferences of the voter, but low familiarity of its complicated computation system has restricted its popularity to a few countries - Ireland, Malta, and the Australian Federal Senate. For that reason, STV would be a hard sell in Africa, and no country is presently applying it there. 20 The Electoral Commission of Kenya 1.4.3 Mixed Electoral Systems The subset of Mixed Member Proportional representation combines aspects of PR with those of plurality/majority systems in the electoral process. The “Parallel” PR and plurality majority sub-system was used by 21 countries in 2005 - including Japan, Thailand, Lithuania, and South Korea. Voters cast two separate ballots, one indicating party list choice under the PR system, and another a preferred constituency candidate under a plurality or majoritarian formula. Outcome in one does not affect the other. In Africa, Guinea-Conakry and Seychelles use the FPTP alongside PR. In other countries, the two systems are integrated, as is the case in Germany, Italy, Hungary and Mexico. In principle, one round of ballots is cast for candidates on a plurality/majority basis and then PR seats (amounting to a certain percentage of total seats in the legislature), are then allocated on a PR formula determined by party strength as reflected by votes each received. In some cases, parties are compensated for votes “lost” under the plurality or majority ballot. The percentage of seats allocated under the PR formula in mixed systems varies. In Germany, it is 50 per cent of the legislature. In Italy it is 25 per cent, 40 per cent in Mexico, and 55 per cent in New Zealand. Lesotho uses the Mixed Member Proportional sub-set and allocates 33 per cent of its legislative seats under PR criteria, and the balance under FPTP. 1.5 Comparing Electoral Reforms and Consolidation of Democracy in Africa: 1985-2005 A t independence, African countries inherited the electoral systems of the departing colonial powers: FPTP for most of Britain’s former dependencies in the continent, and a majoritarian formula with run-off in the former French colonies. Between the 1960s and the post 1989 democratic phase, there has been considerable mutation and innovation. Table II below indicates the systems adopted by 45 countries stood by 2004. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 21 Table II Breakdown of African Countries by Electoral System of National Legislature: 2004 FPTP Plurality/Majority PR Mixed Botswana Cameroon Algeria Guinea (C) Ethiopia Central Afr. Rep Angola Lesotho Gambia Chad Benin Senegal Ghana Congo-Brazzaville Burkina Fasso Seychelles Burundi Tunisia Kenya Malawi Cote d’Ivoire Cape Verde Nigeria Djibouti Sudan Egypt Guinea (B) Swaziland Gabon Morocco Tanzania Madagascar Mozambique Uganda Mali/Mauritania Namibia Zambia Mauritius Niger Zimbabwe Togo Rwanda Sao Tome Sierra Leone South Africa TOTAL 13 13 15 5 Source: Andrew Reynolds, et. al., Electoral Systems Design: New International IDEA Handbook (Stockholm, International IDEA 2005) pp.166-73. 22 The Electoral Commission of Kenya As is evident from Table II, the most popular electoral system in Africa is Proportional Representation in its Party List format. Fifteen of the 45 African countries surveyed by the International IDEA study of 2005 had adopted it. Some of the countries pursuing a PR Party List electoral formula did so out of choice: Morocco, Burkina Fasso, Cape Verde and Sao Tome. This is a result of deliberative democracy in the quest for a better system. But in a considerable number of countries in that category, PR had been adopted as part of the political bargain to bring more political inclusiveness in countries emerging from deep-seated internal conflict based on, among other things, internal social and cultural cleavages. As we have seen, this was prominently the case in South Africa after apartheid, but also in Burundi, Sierra Leone, Mozambique, Rwanda, and Algeria after prolonged civil conflict. Lesotho’s adoption of Mixed System must also be understood as part of her quest for a more inclusive and stable national politics. All this attests to the properties of PR as a conflict resolution mechanism in highly polarised societies. Another point worth noting is that 10 of the 15 states in this category have populations of less than 12 million. Whether large populations with complex diversity make it more difficult to adopt reforms in the PR direction is an issue worth exploring. That countries that have adopted a Mixed System tend also to be comparatively small in size may or may not have anything to do with this observation, but it is worth observing that other than South Africa, Angola, Morocco, and Mozambique are the only African states with populations exceeding 12 million that have adopted PR. There is another story writ large in Table II as well. This one concerns the durability of electoral system types inherited from Africa’s colonial past. Of the 13 countries that elect their national legislatures on a UK-style FPTP, only Ethiopia was not a British colony. The rest were. Of the 13 countries still electing parliamentary delegates under a French style Plurality/Majority system, (with some appropriate local modification) only Egypt was not a French colony. Most of Africa’s population is located in this set of countries -FPTP and the French majoritarian system. This means that the majority of African voters continue to elect their representatives on the basis of electoral rules and The Electoral Commission of Kenya 23 regulations that the countries inherited from their former colonial masters in the 1960s. In short, if Party List PR has become the most popular electoral system among African governments, FPTP and majority run-offs still has the numbers of voters on its side because the largest and most problematic countries in the region are still dedicated to it. These countries are the centre of gravity of African politics. Considering the impact of electoral systems on national politics as discussed earlier, it makes eminent sense for those interested in consolidating democracy in Africa to re-examine the prospects of electoral reforms in these countries further. This brings us to a comparative analysis of democratic consolidation between the PR Party List and Mixed System set of countries and that of countries that have stuck to the electoral systems of the 1960s. Given the characteristics of wide cultural diversity that we observed in the first part of this paper, it is observed that already the largest single category of electoral systems in Africa today is PR, particularly in the Party List format. Even the five African states that now combine PR with FPTP (Guinea (C), Seychelles, and Lesotho), or with the Party Block Vote (Senegal and Tunisia), elements of party lists can still be found. Compared to the countries that have moved towards PR or mixed it with another system, states holding on to the older systems have been less proactive in using constitutional processes and electoral reforms as tools of conflict resolution. Reformers appreciate the potential in these devices, and there have been examples of success derived from that conviction. In line with the criticism levelled against PR, it cannot be claimed that African PR and mixed systems have been vulnerable to the weaknesses generally associated with those reforms - unstable coalition governments, reckless behaviour of extremist parties - than countries still on the older electoral formulas. There is plenty of evidence to the contrary. Low political accountability of legislators to voters in PR and related systems has been a recurring concern in South Africa and Senegal. But on the whole, it is worth noting other aspects apart from the political stabilisation value of PR and Mixed electoral systems. 24 The Electoral Commission of Kenya It would also appear, even though this is subject to confirmation, that democratic consolidation has advanced faster among electoral innovators than among conservatives. Of the 11 countries falling under Freedom House’s “Free” (1-25) classification in 2006, 7 of them—South Africa, Cape Verde, Benin, Namibia, Sao Tome, Lesotho, and Senegal—have either changed to PR or PR in combination with another system. In fact 35 per cent of the countries in this electoral reform category have a ‘Free” classification. Other factors have no doubt been brought to play in making that remarkable transition possible, including statecraft, leadership and appropriate governance structures in the three branches of government. Electoral reforms alone are not sufficient. But it would be safe to conclude that electoral reforms, in partnership with other institutional changes, have made an important contribution to that achievement. What we now need are more detailed analyses to ascertain the extent to which electoral reforms have served as a catalyst for the transition to more democratic rule in Africa. In that process, it will become imperative to undertake closer comparison of the progress in democratic consolidation made by countries that have made innovations with PR or mixed systems with those that have refrained from doing so. In the category of 13 states that have remained faithful to TPFP, for instance, only Botswana and Ghana had reached “Free” status (1-2.5 rating) according to Freedom House in 2006, with “Partly Free” Kenya (3.0) and Tanzania (3.5) being the ones closest to that classification. Indeed some of the poorest democratic governance ratings in the continent are to be found in this FPTP category of states—Sudan, Swaziland, and Zimbabwe. A poor democratic governance record could not and should not be attributed to the electoral system. The fact that the electoral law books have not been honoured in spirit may actually be part of the problem. But at the same time, latent political fears sparked by a winner-take-all polling system in deeply fractured societies are part of the reason behind the reluctance to reform. To the extent that electoral reforms towards more inclusive systems have served to ease transition to more stable and democratic system elsewhere, it would be advisable to study how electoral reforms could help states with low democratisation ratings, and which still hold onto the FPTP electoral formula. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 25 Moving to the 13 African countries that elect national legislatures on the basis of French-style Plurality/Majority systems, only two countries (Mali and Mauritius) were accorded “Free” status by Freedom House in 2006. The ratio of “Free” states to other states in this category is therefore equal to that of the FPTP category, and proportion in both systems (15 per cent) is lower than the one we observed under the group of innovators practising PR or Mixed system (35 per cent). Again, only part of the explanation might be found in the consequences of the electoral system these countries have adopted. The reasons why the worst-rated countries in this category (like Chad, Cote d’Ivoire, Congo-Brazzaville, Gabon and Togo) are where they are in the international democracy league certainly go beyond the electoral systems they have embraced. But as in the low-scoring cases under FPTP, overall reforms in this category too should not leave out changes in the electoral system. 1.6 A Mixed Electoral System for Kenya A s we saw in our review of Kenya’s experience with electoral politics, even under one-party rule until 1988, voters greatly value representatives who are diligent about their constituency responsibilities while consistently conveying voter demands to the Government. These are the reasons behind the high turnover rates at election time. To the extent that one wants to consolidate the gains made by democratic governance in Kenya so far, it would be prudent to maintain single member constituencies in the interests of enhanced accountability of the legislator to the voter. Whether this should continue to be done on the basis of first-past-the-post or a run-off system is an issue that deserves close inspection, bearing in mind that in polarised multi-ethnic constituencies (like most urban areas), second-round polls tend to enhance reaching out more than simple majorities. Having made the case for the continuation of single member constituencies, it is also necessary to examine what complementary electoral mechanism are required to meet the other challenge facing Kenya’s national politics: inadequate representation of women, cultural, ethnic, racial and religious minorities. To deal with this problem, it would be advisable to adopt a parallel 26 The Electoral Commission of Kenya PR system based on party lists targeting these groups. The definition of these minorities, the exact priorities to be accorded each one of these groups, and the proportions thereof should be a matter of inter-party negotiation. In drawing up a scheme for a party list PR system geared to be better cross-ethnic and gender representation, Kenya could draw on examples from other parts of the world that have encountered similar political challenges. Among states observing “mixed FPTP and PR system, Timor-Leste, at one extreme, elects only 15 per cent of its legislature on a single-district FPTP basis and rest on PR. At the opposite end of the spectrum, South Korea allocates 20 per cent of the seats under PR. Of the countries combining FPTP and PR in Africa, Senegal allocates 46 per cent of the total number of seats on a PR basis, compared to 36 per cent for Seychelles, 67 per cent in Guinea-Conakry, and 80 per cent in Tunisia. PR party lists could be “open” (i.e. not specify who the preferred candidates might be) or they could specify gender ratios, as well as excluded ethnic and religious minorities. Under some rules, seats have been reserved for identifiable minorities - as has been done with “black communities” in Colombia, Tuaregs in Niger, “tribes”, and “scheduled casts” in India. This is a potential solution to representation of smallest minority groups in Kenya - Endorois, Ogiek, Barabaig, etc. But it could also be applied to racial minorities that lack political representation even though they play a significant (if not determinant role) in the economy, notably Kenya Asians, Kenyan whites, Arabs, etc. - whose political confidence must be won if rapid economic growth is to be assured. It should be borne in mind that though a combined PR and FPTP bring the advantage of better representation of politically excluded groups, voters find it cumbersome and difficult to comprehend. It also does not guarantee overall proportionality of party or voter-group representation in parliament. Kenyans should not find it difficult to comprehend a “parallel” electoral system. Although Kenya’s electoral system is designated as British-style single-constituency - first-past-the-post - it has always contained a limited “parallel” PR component. After the “communal rolls” were abolished following the second Lancaster House conference of 1962, the Constitution allowed for 12 “Specially Elected Members” of The Electoral Commission of Kenya 27 the House of Representatives. These members, initially nominated by the Governor on the recommendation of the Prime-Minister, were expected to represent critical constituencies that could not have acquired parliamentary representation on a plurality basis. KANU used that device in 1963 to bring in Kenyan European and Asian political leaders (though not women) deemed critical to the transition from colonialism to independence. In addition to key appointments in the Executive and Judiciary, this had the effect of stabilising the free-falling economy, and in reassuring racial minorities during the politically-turbulent juncture of Kenya’s history. In time, “Specially Elected Seats” mutated into “National Seats” serving, under single party rule, the purpose of presidential patronage and the ethnic calculations to buttress an authoritarian government. This went on until the reforms brought into the Inter-Parties Parliamentary Group (IPPG) were implemented in 1997. Without any reference to PR as an electoral device, the IPPG reforms adopted a parallel PR system in effect, by allocating “national seats” to parties on the basis of their share of directly elected seats, rather than the proportion of votes cast as PR calls for. IPPG helped stabilise a violent political phase, especially because of the complementary reforms in freedom of assembly that it contained. Strictly speaking, the Kenyan elections that followed in 1997 and 2002 were run on a “mixed parallel” basis, even though the seats allocated on party-PR basis amounted to only 6 per cent of the total. Consensus should be sought to expand the coverage of the concept using the share of votes cast to a party to decide the number of legislators it is entitled to on the basis of party list based on agreed priority categories. 1.6.1 Complementary Reforms As argued from the start, reforms in the electoral system in and of themselves are incapable of resolving the complicated political problems associated with culturally segmented societies that reflect internal divisions at the polls. In addition to considering electoral reforms along the lines discussed, the country will not make much political headway until some critical constitutional issues are addressed, most of which date back to the 1960s. That they have kept recurring, often with much political passion, is an indication that brushing them aside is no longer an adequate answer. 28 The Electoral Commission of Kenya The first and most important of these is federalism (or majimbo). The 1963 constitution provided for seven regional governments with considerable responsibilities in security, education, health, agriculture, and social services. Experts estimated that 50 per cent of Government responsibilities would be handled at regional level, primarily by district county governments. Regional governments had been allocated some tax responsibilities (vehicle and driving licences, poll tax and land rates), and proprietary rights on local community lands (though not “scheduled lands” which fell under the Central Land Board and could be traded in the market). They also had rights over local minerals and natural resources. The KANU government (like most incoming nationalist parties in Africa at the time) dismantled the system in 1964 in favour of the Central Government. Joseph Murumbi, Kenya’s second Vice-President called regionalism “a ghastly charter of inefficiency, corruption, poverty, and ultimately the suppression of our national aspirations, in which a few people wanted to carve out a little kingdom for themselves under the guise of protecting tribal interests”.31 In one of the most even-handed assessments of that constitution, Ghai and McAuslan said the system was confusing and inherently dysfunctional even for anyone dedicated to devolution: “The regional executives were so designed as not to lead to strong regional governments; they were clumsy and unwieldy; there was a wide dispersion of authority and no clear lines of responsibility”.32 Critics of the Kenyatta government and advocates of majimbo see an ethnic conspiracy in the demise of the system. But they also forget that even after the emasculation of regional authorities, county councils retained considerable responsibility over all primary school education, local health centres, and secondary and minor roads, as the 1963 constitution desired. Municipal authorities and county governments in the economically advanced parts of the country did this reasonably well at this. But as a result of fiscal insolvency (primarily a result of inability to collect taxes) in most of the counties, and inadequate managerial and technical capacity, the situation deteriorated to the extent that the Central Government was forced to assume responsibility 31. Quoted in Sanger and Nottingham, “The Kenya General Election of 1963”, p.16. 32. Y. P. Ghai and J.P.W.B. MacAuslan, Public Law and Political Change in Kenya (Nairobi: Oxford University Press, 1970) p.200. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 29 for these functions in 1970.33 The problem became even more acute after the abolition of the Graduated Personal Tax (under pressure from populist political leaders) in 1974. The tax constituted the bulk of local government revenue. No resistance was offered against the move because the services improved, leading to a declaration of free education in the first four years of primary school in 1974. Yet as a political aspiration in some form, Majimbo did not go away. It made a resounding comeback as soon as the clamour for multiparty politics began in 1990, driving some political leaders from the former KADU regions to demand its return and with it, whole expulsion of “non-indigenous” communities, especially in Rift Valley Province and the Coast.34 The result was a series of “ethnic clashes” in these regions. The clashes left 1,500 people dead and approximately 300,000 internally exiled. Majimbo, in the guise of political “zones”, was an integral part of the “Bomas” Draft Constitution of 2004, which was federalist in character and in intent. Bomas and its Majimbo component was an integral part of the political platforms of the leading presidential aspirants from the Opposition Orange Democratic Movement (ODM) in the run-up to the 2007 elections - Raila Odinga, William Ruto, Musalia Mudavadi, and Najib Balala. In view of its durability as a political demand, primarily in the quest of intercommunal equality, it would be advisable to seek accommodation - as Lijphart and Young recommend - based on a negotiated agreement on the key Majimbo demands: (i) security of indigenous land rights and a limit to cross-ethnic migration and settlement; (ii) local entitlement to benefits from natural resources; and (iii) fiscal federalism. Of the three, fiscal federalism is the least understood and the one that deserves detailed study. Not only was an inadequate fiscal base a major problem in derailing regional (and county) government in the 1960s but also the issue has been subject to endless misunderstanding and speculation from that 33. Republic of Kenya, Development Plan, 1970-74 (Nairobi: Government Printer, 1970), p.14, and pp.179-182. 34. See Throup and Hornsby, Multiparty Politics in Kenya, pp.188-203. 30 The Electoral Commission of Kenya time to the present.35 A lot of that has to do with the confusion between equitable distribution of incomes, and fair shares of public expenditure; and profound misunderstanding about sources of taxation (as it is and as it should be under federalism), without which no public expenditure is possible. All these issues now need to be fleshed out for all concerned to make informed judgements. Despite this, these problems can be resolved using well-tested institutional devices in the construction of federal states, or government in which constituent regions exercise considerable autonomy at political and fiscal levels. And this can be combined with discussion on electoral reforms already discussed, using data-informed policy analysis on devolution and federalism as it would apply to Kenya. For classic Majimbo-type devolution - not the ethnic cleansing and land-grabbing associated with it in Kenya - a compromise solution that is acceptable to regions in favour of federalism and those who detest it can be found. Just as it is advisable for Kenya to adopt a mixed electoral system, it would also be in the interests of the country to try a multiple devolution system, allowing regions (or contiguous districts) to opt for internal self-rule, or government by the centre. That way, nobody would be governed under a system they do not desire. India, Britain (following devolution in Scotland and Wales), USA and Canada, among many other countries, have multiple devolution systems in which regional (or state) government do not duplicate each other. It has been Africa’s misfortune to seek for “one-size-fits-all” solutions in societies as pluralistic as ours. Apart from ethnic rivalries, this has been the source of political animosity and bloodshed. Kenya’s reforms should aim at stopping that by giving space to different systems of local rule. 35. Since mid-2006, journalists sympathetic to ODM and ODM presidential contestants have, in thinly-veiled ethnic allusions, presented figures purporting to show that Central Province (Kikuyu) makes among the lowest contributions in taxation to the exchequer (Shs.1.8 billion), compared to Shs. 6.9 billion from Nyanza (Luo,Gusii, Kuria), Shs. 5.5 billion from Western Kenya (Luhya), Shs. 5.6 billion from Rift Valley (Kalenjin, Maasai, Samburu, Pokot, Kikuyu), Shs. 2.7 billion from Coast (Mijikenda, Swahili), Shs. 920 million from Eastern (Kamba, Meru, Embu, Boran, and others), and Shs. 43 million from North Eastern (Somalia). See Barrack Muluka “Devolution can cure skewed distribution of national wealth”, The Standard, 22nd July 2006. While contributing among the least, Central Province is said to draw more from Government than the rest. Versions of this have been repeated by presidential aspirants Kalonzo Musyoka and Najib Balala. To start with, the total State revenue included in those figures (Shs. 23.7 billion) amount to merely 7 per cent of total recurrent revenue accruing to the Government in the 2004/05 financial year (Shs. 235billion). Kenya Revenue Authority does not categorise sources by region, rather by function (income tax, excise, company tax, VAT, customs) which are obviously concentrated in regions with the highest values of productivity and trade Nairobi, Central Kenya, Central Rift and Mombasa. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 31 1.7 Conclusion T his paper began with an acknowledgement of the gains made by Kenya in process of democratisation from 2003 onwards, without glossing over the new challenges that have risen in the wake of that progress. Against the backdrop of the highly pessimistic literature on electoral studies of Kenya covering the period 1992 and 1997, this indicates there are some inner strengths in the political system that were side-tracked by the analysts. Even if one attributes the success to luck and personality, the argument still holds: failure to seize golden opportunities and moral character defaults consistently appear in that literature as explanatory factors of the tragedy. This time the obstacles were overcome in a peaceful, widely-hailed transition. The principal lesson in that transition was that the power of an ethnically-inclusive grand-coalition, of the kind mentioned by the democracy in plural societies literature, to broad-based victory and widely-accepted national government. Grand-coalition government is one of the governance devices. Kenya’s failure to sustain that coalition must count as one of the many challenges that must be overcome as the country makes effort to consolidate democratic governance in the long run. The other challenge, which was the focus of this paper, is electoral reform - towards more inclusiveness through a formal espousal of a “mixed parallel” election system containing a substantial negotiated segment of Proportional Representation. Both reforms may be necessary but not sufficient conditions for further democratisation of Kenya. Constitutional devolution that accords regions more fiscal and political responsibilities has been on the agenda for too long to be ignored. That it is a tested response to the chronic ethnic politics of the kind Kenya has is one more reason to take it seriously. To ensure that it maximises the gains of those who advocate it, without jeopardising the interests of those that resent it, a multiple devolution system would be advisable with districts (or regions) making a popular choice between different but compatible systems of local governance. To the greatest extent 32 The Electoral Commission of Kenya possible, majoritarian, plebiscitary and “winner-takes-all” formulas should be avoided at electoral, national governance, and local government levels. The opposite - national uniformity, majority rule, similarity of electoral rules and local government - has been the goal of most African governments as well as their opponents. It has also been the source of much misery, and will continue to be. Plural societies deserve multiple solutions, not similar ones, and Kenya is no exception. That was the central contribution the paper sought to make. In one of the most notable publication on African politics in the 1960s, shortly after independence, the distinguished West Indian economist, W. Arthur Lewis, made a strong warning against the then rising wave of single mass parties and highly centralised government, and elections based on a winner-take-all basis. He made a powerful case for grand coalition politics inclusive as possible of major parties, decentralised or federal governments, power-sharing and autonomy for minority groups. Proportional representation was seen as an essential component of this political statecraft. All this went against the nationalist grain at the time. However he stood by that position because, “African societies were plural societies not class societies” as in the West and the constitutional solutions suitable to the western countries were unsuited to Africa. The position taken by Lewis in Politics in West Africa in 1965 bears an uncanny resemblance to the propositions contained in the formula presented by Lijphart in 1977, and which featured prominently in the constitutional debate marking to the transition of South Africa from apartheid before 1994. It was a transition celebrated by the rest of Africa and the world. Africa’s political experience in the 30 years that elapsed between the publication of Politics in West Africa, which most of Africa ignored, and the end of apartheid ought to be a sobering lesson to all concerned about political instability in Africa and the future of its people. We may never really know what the most appropriate institutional framework for national governance and elections for any country might be. In any democracy that is always The Electoral Commission of Kenya 33 approximated through constant experimentation. We are on safer grounds pointing what to avoid, and in this case the 1960s electoral systems now cry out for fundamental change, as do the national governance structures that go along with them. 34 The Electoral Commission of Kenya 2.0 The Kenyan Electoral System: Comments by ECK Vice-Chairman Gabriel Mukele 2.1 Introduction W hen I received the invitation letter to the workshop and looked at the topic “The Electoral Systems of Kenya” I wondered what it was all about. The stated objectives of the workshop, however, clarified the matter. This paper deals with a few common electoral systems, and does not pretend to cover worldwide electoral systems. The Kenyan electoral system is basically a single member constituency based on “First Past The Post” with very little pretence touching on the Mixed Member Proportional Representation. There are good arguments for and against this system. There are also arguments for and against the system of Proportional Representation. Some countries have combined the two to form the mixed member proportional representation. Germany is one such example. The Kenyan pretence on this line is found in Section 33 of the Constitution which reads:1. Subject to this section, there shall be twelve nominated members of the National Assembly appointed by the President following a general election, to represent special interests. 2. The persons to be appointed shall be persons who, if they had been nominated for a parliamentary election, would be qualified to be elected as members of the National Assembly. 3. The persons to be appointed shall be nominated by the parliamentary parties according to the proportion of every parliamentary party in the National Assembly, taking into account the principle of gender equality. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 35 4. The proportions under subsection (3) shall be determined by the Electoral Commission after every general election and shall be signified by the chairman of the Commission to the leaders of the concerned parliamentary parties, the President and the Speaker. 5. The names of the nominees of parliamentary parties shall be forwarded to the President through the Electoral Commission who shall ensure observance of the principle of gender equality in the nominations. I call it pretence because:(a) There is no party list giving the names of those to be nominated for the electorate to know. (b) Those nominated are either friends or supporters of parties and there are some parties in Kenya that are owned by individuals. (c) Nobody pays attention to gender or special interests or particular qualifications of the nominated people. The section can easily be amended to introduce the MMPR system. It can for example provide for 60 unelected members of Parliament of which 40 would be women. The other 20 members would be shared out to cover special interests that would include the disabled, trade union representatives or minorities that would never be represented in parliament through the normal election. The Asian and European communities that bring the number of Kenyan tribes to 44 and not 42 play a major role in the country’s economic development and would hence get a chance to be represented through this system. 2.2 History of the Kenyan Electoral Process K enya achieved its independence from the British by the 1963 Kenya Independence Order in Council. The British set up a constitutional structure that was calculated to take care of the various interests and conditions prevailing at the time. It was a structure that had the potential to ensure the development of a democratic rule. It provided for checks and balances between the various arms of government and it protected fundamental human rights. The constitution provided for a decentralised structure based on 36 The Electoral Commission of Kenya eight regions of the country. Within the regions were county, urban, municipal councils and the City Council of Nairobi, the capital. Kenya was to be an independent multiparty democracy with the Upper House or Senate and the Lower House of representatives. Having acquired independence, the ruling party or class set out to dismantle the system and centralise power. The federal structure of governance was abolished in 1964 and so was the bicameral legislature. This was followed by the shift away from multiparty democracy to a one party state with the political power heavily concentrated in the presidency. By 1988, the country had become a one party state ruled by the only party, the Kenya African National Union (KANU). The problems that followed the setting up of the new system of government are well known to historians and observers. These are the problems that the current constitutional reform process has been addressing without much success. Kenya has held elections regularly since its independence even if some of the elections, such as the 1988 elections, have been bogus and could be described as selections rather than elections. The first Electoral Commission was set up under section 48 of the 1963 Kenya Independence Order in Council. Its members were the Speaker of the Senate as the Chairman, the Speaker of the House of Representatives as the Vice-Chairman, a member appointed by the Governor General acting on the advice of the Prime Minister and a member representing each region appointed by the Governor General acting on the advice of the President of the Regional Assembly of the region. The regions were eight, therefore, the Commission had eleven members including the Chairman. As the centralisation of power by the Executive increased, so were the functions of the Electoral Commission reduced. Over the years, its only function became the delineation of the constituencies that were directly affected by the administrative boundaries which were set out by the Office of the President. Registration of voters and the elections were carried out by the Director of Elections, a civil servant at the office of the Attorney General. The same The Electoral Commission of Kenya 37 office in the Registrar General’s department later registered political parties at the whims of the establishment. During elections, District Commissioners in charge of districts were the Returning Officers and the clerks under them were the Presiding Officers and voting clerks. Except in the south, Kenya is surrounded by sister states which have experienced serious political upheavals that were more serious than Kenya’s own political assassinations. These countries experienced violent changes in government and in one case, peace has yet to return after 14 years of anarchy. Kenyan leaders and people did not therefore want to see that violence hence under pressure from the civil society and political dissent, the government of the day reverted to multipartyism in 1991. Multiparty democracy in the developing world is impossible without an independent and effective Electoral Commission. 2.3 The Electoral Commission Set Up T he Electoral Commission of Kenya is set up under section 41 (1) of the Constitution that states; “There shall be an Electoral Commission, which shall consist of a chairman and not less than four and not more than twenty-one members appointed by the President.” It will be noticed that while Kenya has the largest Commission in the Commonwealth, indeed it has provisions for the smallest one with four members and the chairman depending on the needs and the circumstances of the day. In fact some Commissioners who died have not been replaced. Until 1997, the number was between four and 12 Commissioners. In 1997, political parties decided to talk to each other instead of talking at each other. They reached an understanding commonly known in Kenya as IPPG (Inter Parties Parliamentary Group). Political parties in the opposition had been unhappy with the Electoral Commission as it was then, believing that since its members were appointed by the President, the incumbent and the KANU party leader, it could not be fair to opposition party activities. They wanted changes in the electoral law that would make the Commission neutral and establish a level playing ground that would facilitate free and fair elections. Thus opposition political parties nominated 10 Commissioners for the President to appoint and the law was 38 The Electoral Commission of Kenya changed to accommodate these additional numbers. The Commissioners became 22 including the chairman. The IPPG agreement on who appoints the Commissioners was never included in law. While it is true that the new inclusion brought more confidence in the Commission, the new Commissioners did not, in practice, act as opposition Commissioners. They have all worked well without regard to the sources of their appointment. It is my personal view that representation of political parties in the Commission would be undesirable for the following reasons:(a) party wrangling could extend from parliament and other fora to the Commission. (b) Commissioners have security of tenure and need not pay attention to those who appointed them. (c) The Electoral Commission is independent as provided in section 41 (9) of the Constitution and like judges once appointed, commissioners must carry out their duties in accordance with the law and the mode of appointment not withstanding. (d) The Commission must be strictly impartial and fearless in the application of the law. (e) There are over 50 registered political parties. Each would want a slot in the Electoral Commission. 2.4 The Electoral Law of Kenya (i) The Kenya Constitution (1998 edition) The Electoral Commission is set up under section 41 of the Kenya Constitution. The chairman is appointed by the President and the vice-chairman is elected by members of the Commission. Both the chairman and the vice-chairman must be people who have held or are qualified to hold office of a judge of the High Court or Court of Appeal. Once appointed, a Commissioner’s position is secure and he or she can only be removed, through a special procedure requiring setting up of a tribunal chaired by a High Court judge. It is the same procedure that applies to the removal of judges from office. After the tribunal The Electoral Commission of Kenya 39 has taken evidence against a Commissioner and given him/her a chance of being heard, a recommendation is made to the President for action. Section 41(9) of the Constitution states that in the exercise of its functions under this Constitution, the Commission shall not be subject to the direction of any other person or authority. The functions of the Commission as set out under Section 42 and 42A of the Constitution and are: (a) Decision on the number, boundaries and names of constituencies in which the country is divided. (b) Review, and where need be, alteration of numbers and names of constituencies. ( c) Registration of voters, maintenance and revision of the registers of voters. (d) Direction and supervision of Presidential, National and Local Government elections. (e) Promotion of free and fair elections. (f) Promotion of voter education throughout Kenya. (g) Performance of such other functions as may be prescribed by law. Section 42 (1) of the Constitution empowers the Commission to determine the number of constituencies into which the country will be divided, yet sub-section (2) thereof gives Parliament power to determine the minimum and maximum number of constituencies into which the country can be divided. During the 1996 constituency review exercise, the Commission proposed that the country be divided into at least 250 constituencies, but the law limited these to 210 constituencies. This is an apparent conflict in the law though the intention may be good. Under Section 42 (3), the Electoral Commission is required, when determining the number of constituencies, to ensure that all constituencies contain as nearly equal number of inhabitants as appears to be reasonably practicable. However, the Commission may depart from the aforegoing principle to the extent that it considers expedient in order to take account of: 40 The Electoral Commission of Kenya (a) the density of population and any part to ensure adequate presentation of urban and sparsely-populated rural areas; (b) population trends; (c) means of communication; (d) geographical features; (e) community of interest; (f) the boundaries of existing administrative areas, and for the purposes of this subsection, the number of inhabitants of any part of Kenya shall be ascertained by reference to the latest census of the population held in pursuance of any law. The Commission reviews constituencies at intervals of not less than 8 years and not more than ten years or whenever directed by an Act of Parliament. At the end of review, the Commission may, by order, alter the number, boundaries or names of constituencies to the extent that it considers desirable, but in accordance with the provisions of the Constitution. The order of the Commission prescribing constituencies becomes effective upon publication in the Kenya Gazette and is not subject to debate by Parliament. (ii) The National Assembly and Presidential Elections Act The National Assembly and Presidential Elections Act (Cap 7 Laws of Kenya), 1998 Edition with regulations and rules made there-under besides the schedules of that Act, gives a detailed framework and procedures of the electoral and registration of electors processes. Section 17A of the Act gives the overall conduct of the National Assembly and Presidential elections to ECK. The procedure for voting in elections is set out in the Presidential and Parliamentary Elections Regulations made by the Commission under section 34 of the National Assembly and Presidential Elections Act. Those regulations still stand except as amended a few months before the December 2002 General Elections. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 41 The law empowers ECK to prepare and maintain a register of electors in respect to all constituencies. Section 34 provides for ECK to make regulations to govern the registration of electors. Significantly, the Act was amended in June, 2002 under the Statute Law (Misc. Amendments) Act, 2002 to provide for continuous registration of electors. Other amendments to the Regulations in the Act provided for, among others, the counting of votes at polling stations, marking of the ballot papers using any mark except those that would identify the voter, and incapacitated electors to be assisted by persons of their own choice. It is important to note that the law under Section 3 of the Act provides for the appointment of staff by ECK. The code of conduct for members and staff of the Electoral Commission of Kenya is also available. Section 3(3) of the Act provides for police officers assigned duties by ECK in the conduct of elections to be deemed election officials, and are subject to the direction and instruction of ECK. This is a very controversial area. Those police officers are not available in sufficient numbers and in practice the Electoral Commission never commands them. I have personally advocated a unit of about three to five per constituency under the overall command of the Electoral Commission through its area Commissioners and election officials. To be specific on registration of voters, the law requires citizens who intend to vote to apply and be registered as voters. The National Assembly and Presidential Elections Act as well as the Local Government Act provide for the registration procedures. The provisions include: • continuous registration of voters (except for the times it is not allowed); • time of claims and objections; • where to register; 42 The Electoral Commission of Kenya • who qualifies or is not qualified to register; • how to register. The ECK is responsible for the registration of voters. The Commission appoints the Registration Officers and their assistants to conduct the registration of voters and compile a register of electors for each designated registration unit. It is the voters’ responsibility to inspect and ensure that their names and particulars are properly included in the register. There are provisions which deal with the loss of the voter’s card, change of residence, transfer, objections and appeals. All objections must be directed to the Registration Officers who receive and deal with them in accordance with the provisions of the law. Appeals must be filed within the provided time from the date of communication of such refusal or decision as the case may be and must follow the set regulations. All appeals must be heard and determined before the polling day. (iii)Electoral Code of Conduct This Code was set-up in 1997 under Section 34A of the Act. While the country’s Criminal laws and the Election Offences Act apply to election activities, the Electoral Code of Conduct specifically deals with campaign activities. It is the fourth schedule to the Act. It applies to political parties, candidates and the government of the day. Its objective is to “promote conditions conducive to the conduct of free and fair elections and a climate of tolerance in which political activities may take place without fear of coercion, intimidation or reprisal.” Paragraphs 5 and 6 of the Code outline what participants in the election undertake to do. ECK is empowered to enforce the Code and impose sanctions by way of warnings, fines, limitation on campaign activities or disqualification through The Electoral Commission of Kenya 43 court action. It can, through a court order, bar a party or candidate from taking part in the election. The Electoral Code of Conduct was first enforced during the 2002 General Elections when the Electoral Commission set up the Electoral Code of Conduct Enforcement Committee chaired by the vice-chairman. The committee summoned political parties/candidates and heard evidence concerning complaints from opponents or as provided by observation by electoral officials and the press, e.g., vote buying and electoral violence. The ruling party was fined and so was a candidate of one opposition party. It has not been easy to enforce the Code for the following reasons: (a) The campaign period is so tense and activities move so fast that organising the hearing of disputes and getting witnesses becomes a problem. (b) Taking the matter to court in order to bar a party or candidate from taking part in the election or campaign is difficult, knowing how slow court processes yet everyone blames the Commission for failing to take drastic action against the offenders. It has been suggested that the legal provisions requiring court orders should be removed and the power be given to the Electoral Commission to handle the malpractices at that time. The Commission should deal with disputes before the declaration of results. It should have power to cancel an election before the formal declaration and gazettement of the said result. The court would take over immediately after election results are announced and whatever the Commission would have done would form part of the election petition issues. (iv) The Local Government Act (Cap 265 Laws of Kenya, 1998 edition) In this Act, there are provisions giving the Electoral Commission powers to establish electoral areas. It has rules that govern Local Government Elections outlined in the 5th Schedule thereto, besides sections 10, 53 44 The Electoral Commission of Kenya to 53(c), 57 to 61 of the Act. It also provides rules for the registration of electors and the preparation of a voters’ roll. Some of the qualifications and disqualifications for one to register as a voter differ from what is provided under section 43 of the Constitution. For example, a voter in a local authority has to be on the roll of rate payers. In practice however, these differences are not adhered to during registration of voters. (v) The Election Offences Act (Cap 66 Laws of Kenya) This Act details the election offences and punishment for breaches. It was meant to cover offences and illegal practices at elections and in the registration of electors. (vi) The Societies Act (Cap 8 Laws of Kenya) This Act provides for registration of political parties. The Electoral Commission working with the Kenya Law Reform Commission, the Attorney General’s Chambers and an NGO working on democratization, drafted the Political Parties Bill of 2005. That Bill was to streamline the registration and operations of the political parties. It is still stuck somewhere. It is common knowledge that in most commonwealth countries except Tanzania, the political parties are registered by the Electoral Commission which also controls their funding. The Bill in question provides for funding of the political parties by the Treasury. (vii)The Public Order Act (Cap 56 Laws of Kenya) This Act makes provision for the maintenance of public order at public meetings (rallies) and campaigns. (viii)The Kenya Broadcasting Corporation Act (Cap 221 Laws of Kenya) The changes in the Act were to facilitate access to the public media by various political parties and candidates. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 45 (ix) The Penal Code (Cap 63 Laws of Kenya) Most of the offences concerning elections are also offences in the Penal Code. This is particularly so when looking at the Election Offences Act. 2.5 The 2002 General Elections T he 2002 general elections were historical and positive in many respects. The positive aspects included:(a)Counting was done at polling stations, party agents got copies of polling results documents at the polling station. In fact, political parties quickly relayed information and got results before the Electoral Commission got them. The changes eliminated previous suspicion on possible stuffing of ballot boxes enroute to the counting halls, etc. (b) The Electoral Commission set up the Electoral Code of Conduct Enforcement Committee that summoned parties and candidates reported to be infringing the Code of Conduct. The ruling party itself and a candidate of the opposition party were heavily fined and many other candidates were warned. (c) The training of election officials was good. The training materials were produced and distributed in time. (d) There were several election guides that were specific for Returning Officers, Presiding Officers, polling clerks, candidates and voters themselves. (e) The computerised registers and information facilitated the smooth transition of the vital documents and information. (f) The set up of the result and media centres gave the elections the necessary transparency and credibility. The negative aspects were inter alia:(a) The chaotic nominations in that a political party could end up forwarding two or more nominees at the close of the nomination time hence the burden was on the Electoral Commission to get to the party leaders. There was a complete lack of intra party democracy and gender sensitivity in the nomination of candidates. 46 The Electoral Commission of Kenya (b) The new election rules were approved by parliament three or so days before parliament was dissolved. This put pressure on the Electoral Commission to digest and educate political leaders, candidates, election officials and the electorate. (c) The lack of an empowered conflict resolution body that would deal with conflicts as they arose without going to the law courts during elections. The courts should ideally take over after the announcement of results. (d) The merging or making of agreements among political parties a few days before the formal nomination, hence the confusion as to who were the candidates of the emerging unity or agreement. Opposition parties came from the new political party yet their old political parties were still validly registered. (e) The breakup of political parties on the eve of the elections and lack of clear legislation governing these activities. While the 2002 elections went on reasonably well and were viewed positively by Kenyans and some observers alike, the latest by-elections showed that all was not well for the democratisation process. It is a pity that some of the very people who fought hard for the current democratic space are the same people who want the situation to revert back to what it was during the elections of 1988. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 47 2.6 K Conclusion enyan politicians are notorious for wrangling and making decisions, if any, at the last minute. Constituency reforms and by extension electoral law reforms can all be finalised in one month, if there is goodwill. The regulations that brought the counting of votes to the polling stations, the process that eliminated tampering with election results were legalised by parliament three or so days before it was dissolved. The same group that worked on the aforementioned Political Parties Bill has been working on the Elections Bill. A third draft is ready and a one day workshop would see it through. It could become law within two months and be operational during the next General Elections. The bill enhances the power of the Electoral Commission in enforcing the Electoral Code of Conduct and resolving conflict with powers to punish the offenders. 48 The Electoral Commission of Kenya 3.0 The Electoral System and Multi-Partyism in Kenya 3.1 A Njeeri Kabeberi ED, Centre for Multy party Democracy (CMD) The Electoral System different electoral system can significantly alter the voting pattern and thus the political process as seen in 1988 when the secret ballot was replaced by the queuing (mlolongo) system. The latter was found to encourage fear and therefore lessen freedom of choice of the voter. Kenya’s current electoral system is typical of electoral systems in former British colonies in that almost all members of the national legislature are elected from single constituencies on the principle of “first past the post.” 3.1.1 Over and Under-representation The electoral system is however controversial because its electoral districts (the constituencies) vary greatly in population and size. In the 210 current constituencies, the least populous electoral district has less than 4,000 people while the most populous district has nearly 302,000. Most districts have populations that are well above or below the mean population of 103,000. This huge variation of population across districts violates the democratic principle of one person one vote. Currently the system allows for residents of constituencies with populations below the mean population to be over-represented in the National Assembly, while residents of constituencies with populations above the mean are under-represented. Kenya’s present configuration of constituencies systematically over-represents residents of the most sparsely populated areas of the country, and under-represents the residents of the most densely populated areas. Residents of arid and semi-arid areas in the Rift Valley, northern, eastern and southern Kenya are over-represented while the residents of western and central Kenya, and especially residents of the capital city of Nairobi, are under- The Electoral Commission of Kenya 49 represented. This pattern of representation was established in 1961 and 1963 when Kenya held multi-party elections prior to independence. The pattern was established because the Kenyan Constitution was (and remains) vague about the criteria for the delimitation of electoral districts. The constitution is vague because it specifies multiple criteria that are often in conflict with each other: • According to Section 42(3) of the Constitution, “all constituencies shall contain as nearly equal numbers of inhabitants as appear to the [Electoral] Commission to be reasonably practical, but the Commission may depart from this principle to the extent that it considers expedient in order to take account of: • (a) the density of population, and in particular the need to insure adequate representation of urban and sparsely populated rural areas; (b) population trends; (c) the means of communication; (d) geographical features; (e) community of interest; and (f) the boundaries of existing administrative areas . . .” If the principle of one person one vote is respected and constituencies are established with equal or nearly equal populations, the principle of establishing constituencies that reflect communities of interest or “sparsely populated areas” will be violated, and vice versa. However, although Kenya’s electoral system has over-represented and underrepresented peoples from different regions for many years, this defect was never a source of controversy during the era of the one-party state (19691991), because it did not affect the distribution of seats among political parties. However, since the return of multi-party politics in 1992, the pattern of unequal representation has been increasingly regarded as “unfair” by political leaders from the western and central areas of the country. In the past, this system seemed to favour the party KANU. 50 The Electoral Commission of Kenya 3.1.2 The Presidency Kenya is a presidential representative democratic republic with a direct presidential election. This method of election gives the president of Kenya enormous power with a positive advantage, especially with regard to the 25% majority vote that the winner has to obtain in at least five provinces. This gives the holder of the presidential office a national image and representation. In the foregoing constitutional debates, the current presidential system has been challenged as giving too much power to one person and there have been calls for the establishment of a prime minister’s office, which would separate power between the head of state and the head of government. 3.1.3 Ethnicity and Representation Kenya’s current electoral boundaries have continued to support an ethnic based electoral process other than for the presidency. For as long as the electoral boundaries are geographically distributed, they will in this country continue to be ethnically distributed. Other than urban constituency boundaries, mainly in Nakuru and Nairobi, most other boundaries are within a province and a district that essentially covers one ethnic group. A change in the constitution with a view to giving Kenyans a different election option may be the solution to this. However, this issue is not currently on top of the list of constitutional discussions and we may therefore continue with this system for many elections to come. The Presidency, however, is the only electoral seat that remains outside ethnic representation because of the 25% clause that requires the president to receive at least 25% votes in a minimum of five provinces. This gives the office of the president a national face. 3.1.4 The Electoral Commission The Electoral Commission has continued to gain strength over the years despite its dismal performance in years gone by. Although the Commission is a constitutional body that existed since independence, its active life in Kenya was only clearly known and felt at the 2002 elections when the first ECK chairperson The Electoral Commission of Kenya 51 was nominated by the then president, Daniel Toroitich arap Moi. In the years of one party system prior to the 1992 multi-party elections, the Commission only existed in name and did not perform any of its duties in the supervision of elections. To date its performance continues to be wanting despite major improvements. There are constant complaints that the Commission does not act on election malpractices. The Commission, however, in its own defence, argues that it does not have enough powers and has to rely on the courts to punish election offenders, thereby delaying justice. 3.2 Multi-Party Politics in Kenya 3.2.1 A Historical Recap T he road to the current multi-party system we enjoy in Kenya has been rough and bumpy. Multiparty politics re-emerged in Kenya after December 1991, with the repeal of Section 2a of the constitution. In 1982 Section 2a had officially made Kenya a one-party state, with the Kenya African National Union (KANU) as the sole legal party. Kenya had been a de facto one-party state since 1969 and had gone through different phases of multi-party and one-party politics since independence. From that date on (1982), all political candidates had to be members of KANU. The re-emergence of a multi-party system in the 1990s initially produced a fractured opposition to President Moi and KANU. After 1991 an important new opposition party, the Forum for the Restoration of Democracy (FORD), which later split into different factions forming a number of FORDs, and numerous other parties, emerged. After two national elections (1992 and 1997) in which Moi won against a divided opposition, various opposition elements formed the National Rainbow Coalition (NARC), a coalition of a dozen parties which included the then little known National Alliance of Kenya (NAK), the Liberal Democratic Party (LDP), Ford-Kenya, the Democratic Party (DP), among others. NARC fielded Mwai Kibaki in 2002 and enjoyed a solid victory to become the governing party. The coalition has since self-destructed and brought in ‘arch enemy’ party KANU to form a government of national unity. 52 The Electoral Commission of Kenya 3.2.2 Coalition Politics With the current political party and election system which allows for formation of coalitions before elections without necessarily merging parties, the party with the majority within a coalition does not necessarily become the leader of government or state. This is what happened in the case of LDP in Kenya in 2002. LDP garnered at least 59% of the 56.1% of the total NARC vote out of the 132 MPs represented in NARC, yet they are currently essentially out of government. The 2007 General elections could become a repeat of this scenario especially with regard to KANU, which is the only party with properly established party structures and membership across the country. It is possible, for example, that KANU may actually get the majority of votes and therefore MPs, but because it may not have the presidency, within the current arrangement, they could easily end up like LDP. Political expediency demands that political parties form groupings that allow them competitive advantage in the elections. We therefore continue to witness, desperate and hastily organised arrangements aimed at winning the next elections. The current system which allows for many parties to exist while at the same time allowing themselves to go into elections through some form of coalition as seen in the 2002 elections, or, as we are witnessing with the formation and registration of ODM-Kenya, actually tend to undermine the very essence of multi-party democracy. 3.2.3 The Two-Party System The question that arises though is; would Kenya be favoured by a two-party system or a more parties system given our level of development? Twoparty systems often develop spontaneously when the voting system used for elections discriminates against third or smaller parties. This seems to be the pattern we are developing in Kenya and as it unfolds, we need to think through the rights of minorities and how these get represented in our fairly weak party system. The Electoral Commission of Kenya 53 Kenyan political parties have suffered from an identity crisis for a long time and as they attempt to redefine themselves, they are constantly engaging in reactive rather than proactive politics operating out of fear rather than strategy. A two-party system as we seem to be gravitating towards, requires voters to align themselves in large blocs, sometimes so large that they cannot agree on any overarching principles. This system easily allows for centrists who have no clear political agenda to gain control. While as we still do not have clearly defined right-wing or left-wing political parties in Kenya, the stage of our political growth requires that we begin to find our ideological footing. Otherwise, we continue to be unable to hold any one party accountable to anything because it can be argued many centrists have no definite agenda beyond gaining power. The party developments as we are witnessing may seem the easy way out, but is a short-cut which will derail rather than move us towards progressive political development. 3.2.4 Ethnicity and Multi-party Politics Two issues also arise around the two party system. Does this system help us get rid of ethnic politics or are we encouraging those very politics? Ethnicity continues to be an issue around elections in Kenya because the constituencies within the existing electoral process are, except for urban areas, within certain ethnic boundaries. It would be interesting to see Kenya with a proportionate representation system or party list system. This system would encourage us to support political parties rather than individuals irrespective of whether those individuals are from our ethnic communities or not. 54 The Electoral Commission of Kenya ISBN 9966 - 7062 - 4 - 0 Designed and Printed by