140201 Predatory Lending (revised draft)
Transcription
140201 Predatory Lending (revised draft)
A Section 6, Frontier Torts White Paper November 26, 2013 Harvard Law School, 1563 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, MA 02138 1 MEMBERS OF THE PREDATORY LENDING POLICY GROUP Steering Committee Hannah Diamond Corey Jones Brian Klosterboer Tort Doctrinalists Yohan Park Adam Rosenfeld Patrick Sharma Historians Mark Thomson Hano Ernst Will Burgess External Situationists Lauren Anstey Jessica Ranucci Ted Hamilton Internal Situationists Habin Chung Monica Mleczko Lisa Marrone Colin Chapman Economists Albert Chen Hudson Todd Jacob (Coby) Loup Policy Wonks Alexander J. Clayborne Patrick Swiber Declan Conroy Public Choice Experts Travis West Sean Cuddihy Ben Levenback Media Analysts Petra Plasilova Bianca Tylek Kellen Wittkop 2 The Frontier Torts Project In the fall of 2013, the 83 students in Harvard Law School’s 1L Section 6 participated in an experimental group project in their first-year torts class. The project required students to research, discuss, and write about a current policy problem for which tort law (or some form of civil liability) could provide a partial solution. Based on their expressed preferences, students were assigned to one of three policy groups: 1. Predatory lending 2. Gun manufacturer liability 3. Casino liability for addicted gamblers Each of the three policy groups consisted of roughly 27 students. Each policy group was further divided into the following nine specialty groups consisting of three students each: 1. Project Steering Committee 2. Tort Doctrinalists 3. Historians 4. External Situationists – or Contextualists 5. Internal Situationists – or Mind Scientists 6. Economists 7. Policy Wonks 8. Public Choice Experts 9. Media Analysts The name and role of each specialty group was purposefully vague, and the role could vary based on the nature of the policy issue itself and the interests and particular focus of students working in the given specialty group. Each policy group drafted a white paper and gave a presentation to the class about their policy problem and possible solutions to that problem. Experts working on each issue visited the class to speak about the topic and their work. At the conclusion of the class presentations, each group led a class discussion and a class vote to select the best policy options. (Videos are available of the class various class presentations.) Each policy group then submitted a final draft of its white paper, informed by research, class presentations, discussions, and votes, and by written feedback from the class and teaching staff. The course was taught and supervised by Professor Jon Hanson and teaching fellows Sam Caravello, Deena Greenberg, and Oded Oren. For more information, contact Jon Hanson at [email protected] or visit the website at http://learning.law.harvard.edu/frontiertorts/. 3 Frontier Torts Terminology Dispositionism is an attributional approach that explains human behavior and outcomes as primarily the result of individuals’ thoughts, preferences, and will. Dispositionism presumes that a person’s behavior reflects decisions and choices that reflect that person’s beliefs, attitudes, preferences, personality, thoughts, and intentions, the details of which he is generally conscious. The dispositionist model assumes a person’s preferences are revealed through his choices, since the actor has the will to choose his actions. Naïve psychology is a model of human thinking and behavior that posits that people are aware of, and able to explicate, theaforces motivating their decisions and behaviors. The dominant naïve psychology model, particularly in western cultures, is dispositionism. That naïve psychology model is also at the foundation of law and pervasive in many of the most influential legal theories, including law and economics. Situationism is an attributional approach that explains behavior, outcomes, and events by looking at situational influences—that is, non-salient internal and external forces operating within and around individuals. Situationism is informed by social science—particularly social psychology, social cognition, cognitive neuroscience and related fields—and the discoveries of market actors devoted to influencing consumer behavior, such as marketers and public relations experts. Situationism is premised on the social scientific insight that the naïve psychology—that is, the highly simplified, affirming, dispositionist model for understanding human thinking and behavior—on which our laws and institutions are based is largely wrong. In explaining human behavior, situationism looks to nonconscious psychological forces and non-obvious contextual behavioral constraints that might shape people’s behavior. 4 TABLE OF CONTENTS Executive Summary .........................................................................................................................6 Introduction ......................................................................................................................................7 History of Payday Loans..................................................................................................................9 The Economics of Payday Loans ...................................................................................................11 How Payday Loans Work...................................................................................................11 Are Payday Loans Efficient?..............................................................................................11 Economic Analysis of Potential Solutions .........................................................................13 Examining the External Situation ..................................................................................................13 The Demographics of Borrowers .......................................................................................13 Mapping the Payday Lenders.............................................................................................14 The Community and Credit Situation ................................................................................15 The Poverty Penalty and the Debt Spiral ...........................................................................15 The Psychology of Payday Lending...............................................................................................16 Poverty Impairs People’s Ability to Make Rational Financial Decisions ..........................16 Lack of Access to Mainstream Banks Encourages Distrust ..............................................17 Payday Lenders Target These Vulnerabilities ....................................................................17 The Shifting Media Landscape ......................................................................................................19 Case Studies in Victimization ............................................................................................19 The Role of Advertising .....................................................................................................20 Payday Lending on Trial ....................................................................................................20 The Situational Borrower Gains Dispositional Power .......................................................21 Public Choice .................................................................................................................................21 Situationist Lenders?..........................................................................................................21 The Anti-Regulation Coalition...........................................................................................22 The Coalition for Regulation .............................................................................................23 Proposed Recommendations ..........................................................................................................24 Policy Solutions .................................................................................................................24 Current Policy ........................................................................................................24 Disclosure as a Solution.........................................................................................25 Preventing Default .................................................................................................25 Regulatory Approaches ..........................................................................................26 Alternatives to Payday Loans ................................................................................27 Litigation-Based Solutions.................................................................................................27 Negligence and Lender Liability............................................................................28 Misrepresentation...................................................................................................28 Product Liability ....................................................................................................29 Abnormally Dangerous Lending: A New Tort?......................................................31 Conclusion .....................................................................................................................................31 References ......................................................................................................................................33 5 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY High-interest usurious lending has existed for all of human civilization, and in modern times has taken the form of payday loans. Payday lending is a subset of predatory lending that involves uncollateralized short-term, small-dollar loans. Borrowers take out a loan by writing a check to a lender for the amount borrowed plus fees. The borrower must repay the entire amount on the next payday, usually between two weeks and a month after taking out the loan. If a borrower is unable to pay the entire principal, the borrower can generally pay to have the loan renewed or take out a new loan.1 Payday loans present a number of issues. Unlike borrowers of larger collateralized loans, payday borrowers are not required to demonstrate virtually any ability to pay back a loan. In many states, the only requirement is that a borrower has an income and a bank account. These loans also have excessively high interest rates, which can be up to 780% calculated per year.2 This can lead to a devastating debt spiral in which borrowers sink deeper into debt as they attempt to pay back their loans. 3 After the 2008 financial crisis, the media has increasingly portrayed borrowers in a more situational light.4 This change in framing has opened the doors to possible policy and tort solutions to predatory small-dollar loans. From a policy perspective, states can place outright bans on small-dollar loans, but that might push borrowers to other problematic alternatives. There are other policy options, however, that would allow payday loans to function in a less predatory manner. The balloon payment structure could be replaced with an amortizing schedule resembling more traditional loans. Interest rate caps could ensure that lenders do not demand triple-digit interest rates. The system could also be made more transparent so that borrowers would truly know the risks of borrowing. Torts may present a solution either within existing tort doctrine, or by creating a new tort. Potential plaintiffs may be able to sue payday lenders based on misrepresentation or negligence. If the loans were viewed as products, borrowers could sue under the theory of products liability as well. Creating a new tort could be the strongest way to address predatory lending. The tort of abnormally dangerous lending would serve as an ex-post way of preventing borrowers from entering a debt spiral. Both borrowers and lenders would present their stories to a neutral factfinder who would determine if a loan had been abnormally usurious. If the loan was found to be abnormally usurious, the borrower would have to pay back the principal but none of the fees or interest. 6 INTRODUCTION Arthur Jackson is a retired warehouse worker who lives with his family in North Carolina.5 One day he was leaving the grocery store when a neighboring store caught his eye. Advance America: Cash Advance. Mr. Jackson did not need a cash advance that day, but he thought that a loan might help his daughter further her dream of starting a small beauty shop. The clerk at the store said it was a great idea. All Mr. Jackson needed was a bank account, proof of income, and a driver’s license. He could get $200 in fifteen minutes. Mr. Jackson left the store with $200 in cash but little understanding of how the loan could be repaid. When he received his paycheck two weeks later, he returned to the store to devise a payment plan. The clerk told him that the loan could only be paid in full, but for a small $35 fee the company would roll the loan over to the following month. Every two weeks, Mr. Jackson returned to Advance America to pay the $35 fee. He assumed that some of his payments were paying off the loan, but interest was actually compiling on the principal. Five years later, Mr. Jackson had paid over $3,000 in fees and interest but still had not paid off the loan. And because the principal had grown, the rollover fee had increased. After struggling to pay his bills for several m o n t h s , M r. J a c k s o n f i l e d f o r bankruptcy. Mr. Jackson’s tragic experience is not atypical of broader trends in payday lending. With 2,500 locations across the country, Advance America is the nation’s largest payday lender.6 Together with its in-store and online competitors, the company has provided more than 19 million Americans with short-term, smalldollar loans.7 According to Advance America’s website, these loans help “hardworking families . . . manage short-term financial challenges.”8 While some economists and business executives defend payday lending as providing an efficient and necessary service for working-class Americans, the weight of evidence supports a different story. With average annual interest rates above 400%,9 payday loans have been called “predatory” for a number of reasons. These loans typically target vulnerable populations: the poor and working class, single mothers, racial minorities, home renters, and people without a college degree. 10 Some lenders also obscure information about the loans by implicitly and explicitly concealing the terms of repayment, which allows the lenders to amass large amounts of fees from a small initial outflow. This “lucrative” strategy results in $2.6 to $3.4 billion in annual profit for the payday loan industry. 11 Modern payday lending emerged in the 1980s and grew in the 1990s as most states rescinded interest rate caps on loans as part of broader 7 Mr. Jackson’s tragic experience is not atypical of broader trends in payday lending. While some economists and business executives defend payday lending as providing an efficient and necessary service for working-class Americans, the weight of evidence supports a different story. deregulation efforts. Prior to the 2008 financial crisis, the media rarely discussed payday lending. In the absence of media coverage, people perceived borrowers as dispositional actors who took out loans they could not repay and lenders as situational actors who set their interest rates based on risk. However, just as the Great Depression led to a shift in attributional frameworks that positioned people as situational actors, so too did the 2008 crisis shift the public perception of payday lending. Instead of portraying borrowers as dispositional agents, the media started to see them as products of situation, whose financial ruin was caused by external forces beyond their control. Conversely, the image of payday lenders shifted from that of passive businesses responding to situations to that of active loan sharks preying on vulnerable customers. As we saw with Mr. Johnson, payday loans can have devastating effects on borrowers’ lives. A borrower can lose thousands of dollars from a single loan, and most customers take out multiple loans. A lth o u g h th e lo an s ar e o f ten advertised as emergency cash advances, the industry encourages repeat borrowing from “loyal customers.”12 The average borrower takes out eight loans per year and spends $520 on fees, while the “heavily indebted” borrowers, who comprise a third of the market, take out twelve or more loans per year and 8 pay between $1,000 and $2,000 in fees.13 This kind of targeted lending and the resulting chronic debt has given ammunition to a coalition of consumer advocates seeking to bolster financial regulation and curb the vices of the payday lending industry. Consumer activism has been particularly powerful at the state level; eighteen states and the District of Columbia have capped interest rates. Similarly, the newly established Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) began reviewing procedures to regulate “shortterm, small-dollar” loans in 2012.14 However, payday lenders have adapted to this shifting landscape by seeking new methods to reach customers, often through the Internet and Indian reservations. While a 2012 Frontier Torts white paper explored the behavior of alcohol companies exploiting Indian reservations, some payday lenders, like the infamous Western Sky, are owned and operated by Indian tribes, which adds further complexity to the already fragmented state-by-state regulatory framework. 15 This white paper considers several responses to predatory payday lending: requiring clear, transparent terms of agreement to be provided to all borrowers; regulating the interest rates, frequency, or structure of the loans; expanding alternative access to credit for vulnerable populations; collateralizing loans; and requiring lenders to perform due diligence checks on potential borrowers. While these solutions would deal primarily with statutory law, tort law might also be able to play a role in addressing the harms of payday lending. Currently, financial services providers have no legal duty of care to their clients, but shifting perceptions on predatory lending could lead to the creation of a cause of action for negligence on the part of lenders. Another tort option relies on the doctrine of misrepresentation, which might allow plaintiffs to be compensated if they were intentionally or negligently told false statements when they signed up for loans. Another tort frontier concerns products liability. This new approach could establish compensation for victims based on theories of negligence or strict liability, even though products liability compensation has traditionally been limited to physical damage to a person or property. Finally, this white paper also proposes the creation of a new tort doctrine for abnormally dangerous lending, which would require lenders to exercise a higher standard of care while taking the borrowers’ situation into account. I n r e a l i t y, a m u l t i f a c e t e d approach that involves both regulation and tort law may be the best way to mitigate the harms of payday lending. Such an approach will hopefully be strengthened by a situationist analysis of payday lending. HISTORY OF PAYDAY LOANS The exorbitant interest rates normally associated with payday lending are no stranger to history. In many societies, usury has been illegal and strongly discouraged by social stigmas attached to it.16 Modern payday loans are a relatively recent occurrence, rising to prominence in the late 1980s and early 1990s.17 However, historical accounts of similar practices of expensive, small-loan consumer financial products can be traced back to nineteenth-century salary lenders’ use of wage assignments as security for repayment.18 Unlike the simple Shylockian lender, the payday lender emerged as a character in the postindustrial age, in which he attached to the wage paid “not at the end of the harvest but every week or month.”19 Central to this loan-sharking20 business model was the idea of securing a continuous stream of payments from a debtor unable to pay off the principal for an extended period of time.21 Coupled with targeting the needy, these practices could very well be labeled as predatory. While attributional frameworks of borrowers and lenders were shaped by the Gilded Age and Social Darwinism of the late 19th century, 22 the progressive era challenged these attributions and brought more regulation in the form of the Uniform Small Loans Act. 23 Although not without controversy, 24 the Act sought to control small loans by allowing only a privileged class of lenders to lend at rates above the standard usury caps, thus seeking to 9 In reality, a multifaceted approach that involves both regulation and tort law may be the best way to mitigate the harms of payday lending. attract “honest” businessmen.25 The main benefit was informational; it required transparency and disclosure, but condoned a relaxed—although not unrestricted—interest rate.26 This same rationale also influenced the Truth in Lending Act, passed in 1968, which required standardized disclosures of a loan's calculated costs and charges.27 While many state legislatures have started regulating payday loans by capping interest rates and regulating loan structures, there is still considerable resistance to reinstating strict usury laws. Modern payday lending emerged in the 1980s and is linked to the expansion of the consumer financial system, particularly to the widespread use among all social strata of checking accounts against which the checks to payday lenders were written.28 Subsequently, a large majority of states legalized payday loans.29 Two crucial legal developments coincided with the advent of modern payday lenders: one judicial, the other statutory. The former was the 1978 landmark Supreme Court decision Marquette Nat’l Bank v. First of Omaha Serv. Corp. et al.30 The Court held that interest rates charged by a national bank are bound only by the laws of the state in which the bank is chartered and are not restricted by the usury caps in the customer’s home state. Although the case concerned credit cards, it led to a race to the bottom among states, which removed usury caps in order to attract business.31 The latter development was the 1980 passage of the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act,32 which introduced exemptions from state 10 usury caps for federally chartered savings banks, installment plan sellers, and chartered loan companies. Even though banks are not the primary providers of payday loans,33 these laws have complicated, marginalized, and watered down remaining usury laws to a level of persistent non-enforcement.34 As a consequence of these developments, today's consumer faces a patchwork of very different state laws and is still vulnerable to harmful payday lending operations.35 While many state legislatures have started regulating payday loans by capping interest rates and regulating loan structures, there is still considerable resistance to reinstating strict usury laws.36 At the federal level, the government has generally shied away from regulating payday loans entirely. The Talent Amendment to the Military Lending Act of 2007 is a notable exception.37 Applicable only to military personnel and their families, it prohibits lenders from charging an APR above 36% for payday loans and mandates that both written and oral explanations of the terms of a loan must be given.38 Military members are especially frequent consumers of payday loans due in part to the Uniform Code of Military Justice’s stipulation that military members can be forced to forfeit their security clearance if they incur excessive amounts of debt.39 The Talent Amendment suggests that Congress is aware of the dangers posed by payday loans and is willing to protect at least one class of people from harmful effects. Even so, payday lenders have adapted to the new law by offering both larger and longer loans that fall outside of the amendment’s regulatory scope, demonstrating the industry’s malleability and resistance to reform.40 paid a $35 fee to roll the loan over. Most payday loans take this form.42 • THE ECONOMICS OF PAYDAY LOANS HOW PAYDAY LOANS WORK Following the deregulation of the 1980s and 1990s, payday loans emerged as a category of financial products that is highly profitable for lenders and frequently detrimental to borrowers. In the typical case, a customer writes a personal check made out to the lender. The lender agrees to hold the check for a specified period of time, normally until the customer’s next payday or for about two weeks. The lender then gives the borrower cash equal to the face value of the check minus a loan fee. Typically this loan is: • High-interest: For example, the $35 fee on Mr. Jackson’s $200 loan made for an effective annualized interest rate of about 450%. Lenders usually charge $15 to $20 for each $100 that they advance with a two-week maturity, amounting to a typical annualized interest rate of about 400%.41 • L u m p - s u m : M r. J a c k s o n w a s required to pay back the entire principal of the loan all at one time rather than in periodic installments. For every two-week period that he could not pay back the principal, he • Hassle-free: All Mr. Jackson needed to get his loan was a bank account, proof of income, and a driver’s license. He put up no collateral, and there was no credit check or other form of due diligence that other types of lenders often perform. This is typical in the payday loan industry. 43 Over-simplified: Because getting a payday loan is so quick and easy, borrowers often enter the store motivated to undervalue the loan’s costs and leave the store with a limited grasp on the loan’s terms. 44 The federal Truth in Lending Act does require payday lenders to disclose basic details such as fees and annualized interest rates,45 but the ease of the transaction appears to make borrowers susceptible to ignoring or misunderstanding details. One study showed that 72% of borrowers did not know their loan’s annualized interest rate, and of those who thought they did know, fewer than half reported figures that corresponded to the usual rates actually charged by payday lenders.46 ARE PAYDAY LOANS EFFICIENT? A fundamental principle of economics is the idea that “resources tend to gravitate toward their most 11 Following the deregulation of the 1980s and 1990s, payday loans emerged as a category of financial products that is highly profitable for lenders and frequently detrimental to borrowers. If payday loans were not an option, people who are in need of cash and unable to get a cash advance might turn to even worse channels for borrowing. valuable uses if voluntary exchange— a market—is permitted.”47 When social value is thus maximized, the market for a value or service is said to be “efficient.”48 Applied to payday lending, economists who accept this view would argue that both the lender and the borrower have assessed their alternatives and have come to a rational, value-maximizing agreement. One might doubt this after reading about the injuries and indignities that borrowers like Mr. Jackson suffer, but classical economists have responses to these concerns.49 One such response relies on the concept of “substitution effects.” If payday loans were not an option, people who are in need of cash and unable to get a cash advance might turn to even worse channels for borrowing, including black market loan sharks, checking account overdrafts, or simply not paying bills. For example, one study from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York found that after Georgia prohibited payday loans in 2004, households in the state “bounced more checks after the ban, complained more about lenders and debt collectors, and were more likely to file for bankruptcy under Chapter 7.”50 Another response of classical economics is that the high interest rates attached to payday loans reflect the high amount of risk the lenders are assuming; if lenders could not charge such rates, the argument goes, the transaction would not be valuable enough for them to 12 participate in the voluntary exchange that results in the loan.51 These efficiency arguments can be hard to refute, but they can be equally challenging to prove. The difficulty with such arguments is that they rely not on empirical data but on assumptions about how the world works. And in many cases, one can plug contrary but equally plausible assumptions into the equation and come to a different conclusion about efficiency. One particularly significant assumption that underpins classical economics arguments is that market participants have perfect information. But in the real world, there is no such thing as perfect information and therefore no such thing as perfectly operating markets.52 As transactions get more complex, consumers need more time and knowledge to figure out just how much value to assign to a product or service. In the case of payday lending, research suggests that borrowers tend to rely on information that is far from perfect. Borrowers are likely to be poor and undereducated, 53 unable to understand and evaluate abstract financial instruments with long time horizons.54 A variety of environmental factors, including the aggressive tactics of payday lenders, further complicate the borrower’s efforts to rationally gauge the value of a loan.55 One result of this misvaluation by borrowers is that they do not price shop as much as buyers with perfect information would,56 meaning the market for payday loans does not benefit from the efficiency gains that robust market competition tends to provide.57 ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF POTENTIAL SOLUTIONS In the language of economics, inefficiency is the result of “externalities,” which are conditions in which “one person’s actions affect another person’s well-being and the relevant costs and benefits are not reflected in market prices.”58 In a perfectly functioning payday loan market, most borrowers would refuse to submit to 400% interest rates and balloon repayment schemes, which require borrowers to repay loans in one lump sum. Savvy lenders would also compete to offer more favorable loan terms, thus driving down the market prices of loans. But because borrowers lack information and face other hurdles to effective price shopping, lenders can continue to offer the same extreme lending terms without taking into account the dramatic social costs of plaguing poor communities with payday loan debt spirals. One way to address the payday lending market’s inefficiencies would be to force the market to “internalize” these externalities, or to incorporate the social costs of payday loan debt traps and defaults into the prices of loans. The next question, of course, is which party should be forced to do this internalizing, lenders or borrowers? This white paper suggests that borrowers have trouble internalizing the costs of payday lending; because of poverty, stress, lack of education, and related factors, borrowers often discount the true costs of the loans they are considering. Consequently, these borrowers take out extortionate loans and suffer the consequences later. One can imagine, however, that lenders could easily restructure the point of sale to give borrowers more information about the terms and consequences of the loans. This intuition squares with a concept in economics known as the “least cost avoider,” which suggests that the party who should be asked to avoid externalities is the one who can do it most cheaply 59—or, in the words of a classic formulation of the concept, the one who is “best situated to afford such protection.”60 Later in this paper, we explore in more detail a number of approaches that would force payday lenders to internalize some of the costs that their current practices impose. EXAMINING THE EXTERNAL SITUATION THE DEMOGRAPHICS OF BORROWERS Despite the costs, an incredible number of Americans have participated in the economic model of payday lending. According to a survey done by Pew Charitable Trusts, approximately 5.5% of American adults report having used a payday loan in the last five years.61 In 2010, roughly 12 million American adults used a storefront or online payday 13 One way to address the payday lending market’s inefficiencies would be to force the market to “internalize” these externalities, or to incorporate the social costs of payday loan debt traps and defaults into the prices of loans. A borrower’s story: Fenny from Missouri below show demographic groups took out her first payday loan in the early reporting to have used a payday loan in ‘90s. She didn't have any money, she said, the last five years: and wanted to play bingo. A friend suggested she take out a quick $100 loan. She thought she’d go play some bingo and win. She lost. Two weeks later she renewed the loan, adding about $15 to what she owed. Soon she was taking out loans to pay for other expenses and loans to pay the interest on earlier loans. She took out loans in different Missouri towns until, she said, she “just had them everywhere.” There are more payday lender storefronts in the United States than McDonald’s and Starbucks franchises combined. She got in the habit of taking out loans to address any financial problem, and things got out of control. At one point she had at least five payday loans out at once; another time she turned to auto title loans Figure 1: Demographics of Payday Loan Borrowers 65 to help her keep up with payday debt—and ended up losing her car. MAPPING THE PAYDAY LENDERS Adapted from http://kbia.org/post/payday-loanscredit-option-or-debt-trap, http:// munews.missouri.edu/expert-comment/2011/0125state-report-shows-persisting-problems-withpredatory-lending-mu-expert-says/,http:// www.piconetwork.org/news-media/coverage/ 2009/0246 loan.62 On average, a borrower takes out eight loans of $375 annually, s p e n d i n g $ 5 2 0 o n i n t e r e s t .63 Controlling for other factors, the Pew Report identified five groups with higher odds of having used a payday loan: people without a four-year college degree, home renters, African Americans, people earning less than $40,000 annually, and people who are separated or divorced. 64 The charts 14 There are more payday lender storefronts in the United States than McDonald’s and Starbucks franchises combined.66 A relatively new industry, payday lending grew rapidly in the late 1990s and 2000s — loan volume expanded by about 600% between 1999 and 2004.67 Payday lending locations tend to be small, with average annual revenue of $350,000,68 and rely on customer convenience and familiarity.69 One study estimates that borrowers do not produce profit for a lender until they have taken out four or five loans.70 This encourages lenders to focus on neighborhoods and customer bases that lack alternative credit options and have a high likelihood of repeated borrowing. Payday lenders are 2.4 times more concentrated in African American and Latino communities.71 They have also been accused of targeting military communities in the United States 72 and children in the U.K. though television ads.73 THE COMMUNITY AND CREDIT SITUATION Three larger sociological trends in America could help to explain the current high rates of payday borrowing by creating a real or perceived lack of alternatives to payday loans. Over the past century, Americans have become increasingly mobile. Extended family members are less likely to live together,74 which could decrease the amount of intra-familial lending. Nearly half of payday loan borrowers reported that without the loan, they would not rely on family or friends to get a loan. This suggests that informal family borrowing is not perceived as a realistic alternative for many payday loan recipients.75 Similarly, the decline of civic engagement and social capital in America76 might contribute to an increased reliance on payday loans because of an actual or perceived lack of alternative borrowing opportunities from local sources. This decline in social capital can have an impact on economic outcomes because social networks “connect us to potential economic partners, provide high-quality information, and vouch for us.”77 A decline in locally available credit may have an especially dramatic impact on high-risk borrowers, who are most likely to take out payday loans. The rise of consumer culture and the corresponding norm of consumer credit dependence may also lead payday borrowers to perceive that reducing expenses is not an alternative to payday loans. Credit cards have become very common in American households, leading to a strong perception that borrowing to fund household expenses is socially acceptable. This supports a “defiant . . . consumption culture”78 that makes “immediately obtainable consumption markers whose acquisition was less available to . . . the working and middle classes of previous generations.”79 In one study, 8% of payday borrowers reported taking out loans to purchase “something special” and 81% of borrowers reported that they would cut back on their original expenses if they lacked access to payday loans. 80 This result suggests that the borrowers are using these loans to cover expenses that are, at some level, discretionary. THE POVERTY PENALTY AND THE DEBT SPIRAL While some spending from payday loans is discretionary, many borrowers use the cash advances for necessary and recurring expenses. 81 Because of their vulnerable position, 15 Payday lenders are 2.4 times more concentrated in African American and Latino communities. these borrowers often have little choice but to accept payday lenders’ high interest rates. This is often referred to as a “poverty penalty.”82 In a 2009 study, only 17.5% of borrowers said they had enough cash in the bank to pay for expenses when they took out the loan; 50.6% reported that the payday loan was their only option.83 Because they lack assets and alternative credit options, payday borrowers are especially prone to financial distress. While only 3.9% of all consumers spend 30% or more of their household income on debt service, nearly a third of payday borrowers do so. 84 Payday borrowers are also nearly four times more likely to have filed for bankruptcy within the past five years than other consumers.85 Many borrowers use the cash advances for necessary and recurring expenses. Customers’ precarious financial positions are compounded by the high interest rates attached to payday loans, putting borrowers at risk of falling into a “debt spiral.” An estimated 91% of all payday loans go to returning borrowers,86 and customers that take out 12 or more loans per year account for 60% of the industry’s business.87 Nearly half of a typical store’s cash advances are rollovers or extensions of an existing loan.88 As loan renewal rates go up, so does profitability: older locations with proven customer bases tend to be far more profitable than newer payday lending locations.89 Payday lenders are thus motivated to target financially vulnerable customers likely to become repeat 16 borrowers. THE PSYCHOLOGY OF PAYDAY LENDING In addition to external factors, the psychological conditions impacting borrowers’ decisions help explain why payday lending is such a thriving industry and why the economic model might not be as efficient as economists perceive. POVERTY IMPAIRS PEOPLE’S ABILITY TO MAKE RATIONAL FINANCIAL DECISIONS People tend to over-value immediate rewards over more distant, future ones in a tendency known as “delay discounting.” This undermines rational decision-making in a variety of circumstances, including financial decisions.90 Poverty exacerbates the effects of delay discounting by causing people to focus more on immediate rewards at the expense of long-term returns. This is consistent with Mullainathan and Shafir’s theory of “scarcity,” which holds that money or time scarcity captures people’s attention and impairs rational, future-oriented decision-making. Experimental data bears this out. For instance, in one neuro-economic experiment, people assigned to a mock condition of poverty over-borrowed significantly.91 Scientific findings confirm that stress—in particular, chronic stress and its associated hormones—impair brain functions involved in rational financial decision-making. The pre-frontal cortex (PFC) in the brain is involved in complex cognitive behavior and d e c i s i o n - m a k i n g .92 T h e P F C i s responsible, among other things, for helping people avoid delay discounting. But its functioning is highly vulnerable to disruption. People affected by financial scarcity are more susceptible to irrational financial decisions due to chronic stress induced by their situation, which in turn impairs PFC functioning.93 In addition, those under chronic stress tend to rely heavily on habits, which makes them less sensitive to outcome value.94 In general, poverty, scarcity, and chronic stress impede one’s ability to make sound financial decisions or form reasoned judgments of future financial risk, which is critical in evaluating whether a loan will provide more benefit than harm. Thus, socioeconomically disadvantaged groups are particularly susceptible to accepting payday loans without reasoned regard for the interest rates offered. LACK OF ACCESS TO MAINSTREAM BANKS ENCOURAGES DISTRUST Disadvantaged populations’ lack of access to mainstream banks exacerbates this situation. Mainstream banks have a less developed infrastructure in lower income communities,95 and hence people in those communities lack the protections of mainstream financial systems that are “composed of attractive ‘no-fee’ options, automatic deposits, reminders . . . built to shelter them from grave or repeated error.”96 In 2011, 28.3% of US households were unbanked or under-banked, which means that they conducted “some or all of their financial transactions outside of the mainstream banking system.”97 While some payday lenders do not live within physical proximity of t r a d i t i o n a l b a n k s ,98 n e g a t i v e perceptions of mainstream banking systems also play a role in exacerbating people’s lack of access to credit. Those without access to mainstream financing perceive banks as serving only the better off, creating an ingroup/outgroup mentality that pushes them further away from more m a i n s t r e a m f i n a n c i n g99 a n d encouraging a general distrust of financial institutions.100 Lack of trust creates a negative cycle, further reducing an individual’s desire to conform to social norms and participate in the mainstream financial system.101 As a result, payday loans become an increasingly attractive option and borrowers assume they need to pay a premium to get any access to credit. PAYDAY LENDERS TARGET THESE VULNERABILITIES Payday lenders tend to advertise their product merely in terms of the immediate reward, highlighting the quality that populations with severe scarcity are already predisposed to over-value. 17 Poverty, scarcity, and chronic stress impede one’s ability to make sound financial decisions. Payday loan advertisements often exclusively refer to the gains associated with them. For example, payday loans use taglines like “Get Cash NOW!”102 to ostensibly promise fast cash with minimum hassle. Payday lenders tend to advertise their product merely in terms of the immediate reward, highlighting the quality that populations with severe scarcity are already predisposed to over-value. This type of advertising exploits three additional types of cognitive biases. First, it takes advantage of the “framing effect,” in which people’s A borrower’s story: Domingho started a federal class action against a payday loan store in Chicago. He initially borrowed about $2600, but each of the 9 times the lender renewed or “flipped” his loan, the amount he owed grew. Even though he paid about $5000 over 10 months, he only managed to reduce the principal balance on his loan by $30. The rest was applied to fees. The lender, Dominginho said, set its customers up to fail and then harassed them. In his case, they used an automatic dialing system to call repeatedly about his balance and paperwork, even after he asked them to stop. Unfortunately, Dominginho’s loan agreements contained arbitration requirements and class action waivers. He argued that these provisions were unconscionable and unenforceable, but the court enforced them anyway. Adapted from http://www.courthousenews.com/ 2009/07/14/ Class_Calls_Payday_Lender_a_Shark.htm, https:// a.next.westlaw.com/Document/ Ief59d089d14a11df84cb933efb759da4/View/ FullText.html 18 choices are heavily influenced by the manner in which options are presented. A series of studies have demonstrated that people preferentially choose options that are framed positively. For example, people are more likely to purchase condoms advertised as 95% effective as opposed to those advertised as having a 5% risk of failure.103 Second, it encourages “ambiguity aversion” — people prefer options with more certain outcomes.104 The certainty of immediate cash makes payday loans seem more attractive, especially in contrast with a m u r k y, c o m p l i c a t e d m a i n s t r e a m financial system. Third, it speaks to “time-variant preferences”— preferences for activities that deliver immediate benefits and delay perceived costs.105 Even if advertisements made the risks of payday loans explicit, cognitive biases would still lead consumers to underestimate product risks. “Optimistic bias,” in which consumers view themselves as less vulnerable to a particular risk, militates against full apprehension of the risks of payday loans.106 “Cognitive dissonance” is also at play—people often ignore information that casts doubt on their decisions, such as the decision to resort to a payday loan vendor.107 Making matters worse, payday lenders design contracts in ways that augment these biases. Contract design often minimizes the perceived total price by increasing the price of dimensions that consumers are most likely to underestimate.108 The lender’s strategy exploits the vulnerabilities of low-income populations. In fact, some payday lenders reach out to potential applicants personally.109 Although everyone is susceptible to cognitive biases that lead to outcomes traditionally perceived as irrational, people in vulnerable socioeconomic groups are especially susceptible to the predatory nature of payday lending.110 THE SHIFTING MEDIA LANDSCAPE Since the 2008 financial crisis, the media has begun incorporating the lessons of psychology to reframe attributional frameworks for borrowers and lenders. Media coverage of payday loans was limited before the recession and borrowers were generally assumed to be dispositionist actors. Today, however, most journalistic reports share two characterizations: dispositionist lenders and situationist borrowers. Reflecting these characterizations, articles, videos, and news broadcasts often aim to warn consumers about the danger of payday loans. For example, an article published in Business Insider used the headline “6 Outrageous Facts That Show How Payday Lenders Screw Consumers,” accompanied by a photo of a brightly colored display window of an unnamed lender’s store.111 The brief article gives a summary of payday loans and the controversy encircling the industry. The introduction employs the verb “prey” to describe the actions taken by lenders in soliciting business from borrowers. The lenders are portrayed as taking advantage of borrowers, whose decisions to take out payday loans are shown as products of their situations. CASE STUDIES IN VICTIMIZATION Case studies published by the Center for Responsible Lending illustrate stories of the dispositionist lender and the situationist borrower, detailing the experiences of various “victims of payday lending.”112 In the introduction, Mr. Jackson was referred to as a “26er” by the industry because he renewed his loan bimonthly in accordance with paycheck deposits, resulting in 26 fee payments per year. The same attributional scheme invoked in Mr. Jackson’s saga colors the story of Sandra Harris. 113 Ms. Harris was a successful radio show host when her husband lost his job. When her family could not afford to pay their car insurance bill, she contacted Payday Loans Direct and took out a small loan. She was prepared to pay back the first loan on her next payday, but the clerk convinced her to renew. Soon, Ms. Harris was taking out payday loans to repay previous loans and paying rollover fees on six loans simultaneously. Eventually she wound up facing eviction, her car was repossessed, and her checks started bouncing. The situation came to a head when she found herself sobbing in between segments of her radio show. Despite her successful career, Ms. Harris still feels financially 19 People in vulnerable socioeconomic groups are especially susceptible to the predatory nature of payday lending. behind “because she got caught in the debt trap.”114 THE ROLE OF ADVERTISING The following excerpts from advertisements by payday lenders illustrate the skewed image of payday loans that lenders present to consumers. Loans are portrayed as no-hassle, convenient solutions to recurring problems or emergencies. Lenders portray themselves as an integral part of the community and attempt to establish trust by referencing their history in the community and desire to help their fellow neighbors “breathe” until the next paycheck arrives. “It’s easy!” “Easy!” “Really easy!” “So this time, next time, every time you need cash—Ace Cash Express. Earning your trust since 1968.” Figure 3: “Designed With You In Mind” by Montel Williams for MoneyMutual116 “Would an extra $1,000 come in handy right now? Then I’d like to talk to you about MoneyMutual. It’s your trusted source to over 60 lenders to get you up to $1,000 fast. That big medical bill? Paid! The car? Fixed! Breathing room till payday? Done! [. . .] No credit score required. Need cash tomorrow? Go to moneymutual.com today!” PAYDAY LENDING ON TRIAL Figure 2: “Loans Up To $1,000 in Minutes” by Ace Cash Express 115 “The fridge broke!” “We had to take Buddy to the vet.” “My car wouldn’t start. Again!” “When the unexpected happens and you need cash, visit your neighborhood Ace Cash Express or go to acecashexpress.com. In just minutes, you can get a payday loan for up to a $1,000 with no credit hassles.” 20 The media has also begun to report on administrative and legal issues stemming from recent regulatory action. In its coverage of the lawsuit against Western Sky Financial, the New York Times continuously referred to lenders as gulling millions of helpless borrowers into unsustainable long-term debt and trapping them “under a crescendo of interest costs.”117 In another case, a class action in New Jersey was filed against U.S. Bank for its role in online payday lending and the suit attracted the attention of the Minnesota Star Tribune. Readers were introduced to a “hardworking single mother that lives in the state that has banned payday loans and who paid over 600% APR on a loan.”118 In the eyes of the media, the situationist consumer again fell victim to the dispositionist lender that utilized technological loopholes to evade regulation. THE SITUATIONAL BORROWER GAINS DISPOSITIONAL POWER R e c e n t l y, t h e C o n s u m e r Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) issued a statement on CNBC explaining that it will allow consumers of payday loans to file complaints against payday lenders.119 The CFPB will forward complaints to the payday lenders who will then be permitted to reply. Eventually, the entire complaint will be available in a public database. The CFPB is seeking complaints about the most common payday lending problems, such as unexpected fees, inaccurate fees, and unrequested loans. The CFPB Director, Richard Cordray, says this practice will give “people a greater voice in this market.” The CFPB believes it will transform the situation of the borrowers by allowing them to be more dispositional decision-makers after hearing the complaints of other “victims.” Despite the relatively small amount of historical mainstream media coverage of payday lending, consistent attributional schemas are evident in the portrayal of the industry. Given the large market for payday lending and ongoing implementation of increasingly stringent and consumerminded regulation, the media attention given to payday loans will probably increase in the future, and it is unlikely that the view of borrowers as situational victims and lenders as dispositional actors will change. PUBLIC CHOICE SITUATIONIST LENDERS? With the media’s attributional frames aligned against them, many payday lenders argue that high interest rates are necessary to provide credit to certain populations. When making this argument, they generally cite the high rate of default.120 Most who can pay back their loans choose to borrow elsewhere, which leaves a pool of mostly high-risk borrowers for payday lenders. Because many transactional costs do not increase with the size of the loan, these costs comprise a larger portion of the principal of smaller loans. In addition, payday lenders have many locations and keep longer hours than banks, which are helpful to customers and a necessary part of the business model, but also expensive to maintain.121 Given these factors, payday lenders argue that their interest rates are necessary to maintain viable businesses.122 Even non-profit payday lenders run by credit unions charge similar interest rates of up to 500%. 123 Their customers have few other options: 73% of payday loan 21 Payday lenders argue that high interest rates are necessary to provide credit to certain populations. borrowers have been denied a loan from another source in the prior five years,124 and the few available alternatives, like bank overdrafts, pawn shops, and auto title loans, have similarly high interest rates.125 Payday lenders have an interest in blocking any potential expansion of tort law to cover loans resulting in financial ruin, but such expansion will not necessarily destroy their businesses. Payday lenders have an interest in blocking any potential expansion of tort law to cover loans resulting in financial ruin, but such expansion will not necessarily destroy their businesses. Payday lenders make about the same profits per loan from both high-frequency and lowfrequency borrowers, and a business only making loans to low-frequency borrowers could still be viable, even if less profitable.126 THE ANTI-REGULATION COALITION To protect their interests, payday lenders and their representatives have increased their contributions to national political candidates in recent years. 127 Their federal lobbying expenditures in the 111th Congress alone (2009-10) exceeded $9 million.128 In Texas, where lenders exploit a legal loophole to operate as “credit service organizations,” lenders contributed over $1.3 million to state officials in the 2009-2010 election cycle.129 Comprehensive payday lending reform failed in the Texas House of Representatives earlier this year.130 Other financial institutions feature in the public choice landscape. 22 Firms providing capital for small-loan operators are predictably interested in preserving the system.131 Major banks have also supported the payday loan industry in lobbying efforts. This support could be explained in at least three ways. First, some of these banks themselves offer small-dollar, short-term loans or other similar services. Wells Fargo, for instance, provides Direct Deposit Advances for a fee of $1.50 per A borrower’s story: Lisa from North Carolina was raising her five-year-old daughter alone, with barely any child support. She felt bad about getting financial help from her parents, so when she started seeing payday loan ads and storefronts she was excited to find a new way of making ends meet. The boost to her sense of dignity would not last long. In less than eighteen months, Lisa wound up paying over $1200 on a loan that was supposed to be for $255 because she did not understand the interest and fee terms of the loan she was taking out. When she finally understood what was happening, she said, “I was almost relieved, because then I understood why I was more broke than I was before the payday loans.” To escape the cycle of payday debt, Lisa intentionally bounced a check, terminating her eligibility for new loans. It would take two years more to pay off the check and fees. Adapted from: http://www.responsiblelending.org/ payday-lending/tools-resources/victims-1.html $20. 132 Second, banks and payday lenders share an interest in blocking federal financial regulation. Despite payday lending’s generally unfavorable public image, banks have been willing to join with payday lenders in funding campaigns against the CFPB, for example.133 Finally, major banks can benefit from payment collection for payday loans.134 Although payday lending is presented as a tool for avoiding overdraft fees, 27% of all borrowers and 46% of online borrowers claim to have incurred such fees in the last year as a result of lenders accessing their accounts.135 Overdraft fees constitute revenue for banks—including those that knowingly allow payday lenders to withdraw from underfunded accounts.136 THE COALITION FOR REGULATION Consumer advocacy organizations have tried to develop models for responsible lending and are the largest force pushing for the regulation of payday loans. The National Consumer Law Center has developed criteria to determine what constitutes a responsible loan (such as 36% APR caps, longer loan periods, and alternatives to balloon payments).137 Consumer advocacy organizations have also identified groups that are particularly vulnerable to payday lending. For instance, the Center for Responsible Lending identified military families as particularly vulnerable and encouraged the Department of Defense to limit the types of loans available to them.138 The Center for Responsible Lending’s approach to predatory loans aimed at military families is a good example of how these organizations influence the law. They regularly provide feedback on proposed regulations, as when the Department of Defense considered regulating the types of financing available to military f a m i l i e s .139 T h e C e n t e r f o r Responsible Lending is pursuing a similar strategy in cooperation with the CFPB, which is attempting to regulate overdraft fees (often a complication of payday lending). 140 Their strategies all attempt to shift the debate from the needs of the industry to the impact of payday lending on families who find themselves trapped in debt. Consumer advocacy groups have also spent money opposing payday lenders. In 2008, advocacy groups spent over $1.5 million to oppose a ballot initiative in Arizona to reinstate payday lending after the legislature banned it 141 and to support a ballot initiative in Ohio capping interest rates at 28% and loan amounts at $500.142 That same year, however, a proposed ballot initiative to cap rates at 36% backed by church groups and labor unions in Missouri failed to make the ballot. Payday lending supporters spent $2.8 million opposing the initiative and circulated decoy alternative proposals, which 23 Although payday lending is presented as a tool for avoiding overdraft fees, 27% of all borrowers and 46% of online borrowers claim to have incurred such fees in the last year as a result of lenders accessing their accounts. confused voters about which proposals were real.143 Many aspects of the payday loan writing process are ripe for reform, but rules surrounding mandatory disclosures to consumers are perhaps most so. While consumer advocacy groups are prominent in pushing for regulation, other groups have also signed on to efforts to regulate payday lending. For instance, a report by Arkansans Against Abusive Payday Lending listed the AFL-CIO, NAACP-Arkansas, and the Interfaith Alliance of Arkansas as cosponsors.144 These organizations support efforts to regulate payday lending due to the disproportionate impact those loans have on their constituent groups. While pushing for regulations is not their primary purpose, they have the ability to give credibility and power to the recommendations of consumer advocate organizations, which often lack the direct access that groups like the NAACP and AFL-CIO can offer. Credit unions, whose small loans sometimes face competition from payday loans, have also been known to join labor unions and consumer protection advocates in supporting state-level payday lending restrictions.145 PROPOSED RECOMMENDATIONS disclosures to consumers are perhaps most so. Currently, a baseline of disclosures by lenders to consumers is required under the Truth in Lending Act (TILA).146 These requirements ensure that consumers receive basic information about the loan terms (the amount financed, the APR, the payment schedule, and other key elements) prior to signing.147 But these rudimentary details of the loan terms might not be particularly meaningful to consumers of payday loans, since consumers might not effectively absorb this relatively abstract set of numbers when they are focused on A borrower’s story: When the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau came to Birmingham, Quinn was there. He told officials the story of his 21-year-old sister, who took out a payday loan to buy books. When she found she couldn’t pay off her initial loan, Quinn’s sister decided to get a car title loan. The collateral was a car she had bought with a portion of her inheritance after their mother’s death. Even with the new loan, she couldn’t keep up with payments. In desperation, she stole a check from a family member. As far as Quinn is concerned, a payday loan “killed” his sister. “I haven’t seen [her] in two Christmases,” he says, POLICY SOLUTIONS “because there’s so much shame that she has with the family.” Current Policy Many aspects of the payday loan writing process are ripe for reform, but rules surrounding mandatory 24 Adapted from http://files.consumerfinance.gov/f/ 201201_cfpb_transcript_payday-lending-fieldhearing-alabama.pdf little beyond obtaining cash as quickly as possible. Disclosure as a Solution One solution would be going beyond the comparatively minimal TILA disclosures toward requirements that will better provide loan customers with relevant, contextualized information prior to agreeing to the loans. For example, lenders might be required to present customers with an analysis of a given loan’s near-term financial implications, prepared on a case-by-case basis.148 This would allow a customer to better apply the meaning of the payday loan to her specific context, rather than merely forcing her to face abstract concepts that she might not fully understand or appreciate. Put differently, an astronomically high interest rate may mean one thing to a consumer, while seeing the implications of that rate on her future paychecks and other financial obligations may have a different, eye-opening effect. These disclosure requirements are aimed at better informing consumers so that they might avoid the “debt trap” perils associated with falling into a cycle of payday loans. In addition, we could consider requiring payday lenders to afford customers other product-related types of pre-signing disclosure. One recent proposal in the U.S. House of Representatives focused on requiring payday lenders to remind customers that their products are “not intended to meet long-term financial needs,” that they “should be used only to meet short-term cash needs,” and that lower-cost alternatives for obtaining resources may be available elsewhere.149 Ian Ayers and Alan Schwartz have proposed a similar cautionary requirement whereby payday lenders would be required to disclose and explain the key terms of a loan in a designated warning box; this approach would prevent the lenders from burying the unfavorable aspects of the loan within lengthy contracts. 150 Perhaps more of this sort of disclosure, relating to the general nature of payday loans themselves and the implications of a loan’s terms rather than simply the specific terms of a given loan, could benefit consumers going forward as well. Preventing Default An additional, potentially complementary way to address the issues raised by payday loans in their current form would be to place more of an onus on lenders to preemptively protect their customers from defaulting. As it stands, the default rate for first-time payday borrowers has been shown to be as high as 12%.151 High default rates force lenders to raise loan interest rates, which in turn causes the debt burden on the borrowers to be even greater. In an effort to require payday lenders to exercise due diligence when giving out a loan, we might propose requiring lenders to check credit histories for prior payday loans. Restricting loan access to consumers 25 These disclosure requirements are aimed at better informing consumers so that they might avoid the “debt trap” perils associated with falling into a cycle of payday loans. Restricting loan access to consumers who are not already saddled with large amounts of outstanding debts would ultimately advantage both the consumer and the lender. who are not already saddled with large amounts of outstanding debts would ultimately advantage both the consumer and the lender. Specifically, consumers would avoid assuming a burden they could not manage, while lenders would be able to retain credit that might otherwise have been ruined. Requiring consumers to provide some sort of collateral before securing a loan could similarly trigger this outcome. If payday lenders were forced to require collateral from their would-be debtors, they would not lose the full amount of the loan in the event of a default. Thus, the loans would be slightly less risky and the interest rates on the loans could be lowered.152 On the other hand, high interest rates are not the only problem borrowers face and requiring collateral for low-income borrowers is dangerously similar to pawn shop loans and car title loans, two of the most predatory categories of shortterm, small-dollar loans.153 Regulatory Approaches An alternative policy route would involve pursuing more interventionist approaches. As an example, a number of states have already imposed strict caps on fees and interest rates. These caps generally lead to a precipitous drop in the supply of payday loans in those states. In the year following Oregon’s capping of interest rates at 36% APR in 2007, payday lender licenses in the state dropped from 346 26 to 82.154 From this example, it appears that some lenders continued to issue payday loans with significantly lower rates, but the caps undoubtedly had an effect in significantly reducing the number of payday loans and lender storefronts. Extrapolating from these results, the imposition of strict caps on fees and interests rates on payday lenders seems to offer a direct way of forcing the industry to lend in a more reasonable manner, or to cease doing so altogether. Another highly interventionist approach would involve imposing caps on the size of payday loans. Of the 27 states that provide little other regulation for payday loans, 21 cap the size of small-dollar, short-term loans, usually at $500.155 This seems to imply that these state legislatures acknowledge the potential of exorbitant interest rates to harm their citizens. Though this approach might not eliminate the extortionate rates that payday lenders can charge, it would at the very least mitigate the damages such rates could have on borrowers. Reforming the lump-sum payment scheme could also help protect payday loan consumers from predatory practices. One reason that payday loan borrowers get trapped in a cycle of debt is that most cash advance companies only allow repayment of the loan principal in one lump sum.156 For those living paycheck-to-paycheck, that sort of repayment is often impossible to make, which forces them to pay additional fees to renew their loans. While regulators want to stop payday borrowers from being trapped in perpetual cycles of debt, they also worry that regulating payday loans out of existence will foreclose certain populations from readily accessing credit. A ban on lumpsum repayment schemes could provide a solution to this dilemma. Lenders could still charge whatever interest rate they need to justify the risk of a loan, but they would not be allowed to prevent borrowers from paying off the principal more gradually. If borrowers could pay a few dollars toward the principal every month, they could escape the payday loan “trap” without needing to rely on some sort of outside cash infusion. The overarching dilemma surrounding regulation of payday loans is that overregulation could foreclose access to credit. Economists therefore warn of the “substitution effect,” in which desperate borrowers will face even less desirable alternatives as a result of government interference in this market. Even now, most payday loan borrowers do not have many appealing alternatives. Seventy percent of payday loan borrowers in Oregon said that they did not have any alternative sources to credit when the interest rate cap went into effect in 2007.157 While some borrowers reported that they could cut down on spending, others claimed they would need to max out credit cards or overdraw their checking accounts to pay their bills. Alternatives to Payday Loans A solution to this problem could be to give borrowers better options by providing positive alternatives. The government could encourage or fund the reestablishment of community banks. It could subsidize microloans to the poor, like it currently does for some small businesses through the Small Business Administration.158 Or it could broaden the social safety net so that people no longer need payday loans to fund basic living expenses. Additionally, the private sector might also be able to provide viable alternatives to payday loans. The Grameen Bank, which has revolutionized the developing world with the innovation of microloans, recently started a Grameen America branch that provides microloans to Americans who lack access to capital. 159 With interest rates often above 50%, microloans can still be expensive for borrowers and are often profitable for banks that supply them.160 While the profit margins are presumably smaller than those for payday loans, microlending banks might be able to provide a private sector solution for expanding access to credit. By providing such alternatives, we could ensure that the regulation of payday lending and consequent changes in industry practices would truly be in the best interest of the consumer. LITIGATION-BASED SOLUTIONS In recent years, a number of states have passed laws and 27 A ban on lumpsum repayment schemes could provide a solution to this dilemma. A plaintiff may be able to bring a viable tort claim under theories of negligence, fraud and misrepresentation, or products liability. regulations that address payday lending abuses.161 Although there is a wide variety in state regimes governing payday lending, most efforts have focused on limiting interest rates and service fees, capping the size of loans, and fixing the minimum and maximum repayment terms of loans. 162 As previously mentioned, some states have also required payday lenders to provide more information about their financial products to customers.163 Growing awareness of the problems associated with payday lending has even led the federal government to begin taking steps to address payday lending abuses. The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, passed in 2010, gave the federal government new powers to regulate payday lending.164 As a result, the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency are currently developing rules to govern payday lending.165 In addition to statutory law, civil litigation is a potential solution to the problems associated with payday lending. A plaintiff may be able to bring a viable tort claim under theories of negligence, fraud and misrepresentation, or products liability. We consider these theories below and also propose a new ex-post incentive-based liability tort to combat payday lending abuses. Negligence and Lender Liability 28 Claims of negligence are one potential strategy to deal with the problems of payday lending. In common law, negligence occurs when a defendant breaches a duty to a plaintiff and causes the plaintiff harm. Under this schema, borrowers could bring claims of negligence against payday lenders that either intentionally or unintentionally cause harm by breaching duties of care that are owed to the borrowers. Proceeding on claims of negligence would require that courts expand their understanding of a lender’s duty to care for their customers. In just three decades, the concept of lender liability has “gained acceptance as a substantive body of law.”166 Generally speaking, lender liability law imposes a duty on lenders to treat their borrowers fairly. In addition to honoring the terms of the loan contract, this duty can include honoring any side deals that were not clearly detailed in the loan document, properly renewing a loan, and processing loans in a timely fashion.167 As lending abuses have become apparent in industries like home mortgages, courts have been willing to expand lender liability to encompass a broader array of issues, which has made bringing suits based on a range of other claims, like misrepresentation and breach of contract, easier for victimized borrowers. Misrepresentation Finding certain payday lenders guilty of misrepresentation is another potentially fruitful tort solution to the problem of lending abuse. Misrepresentation can be based on either intent or negligence. The tort of intentional misrepresentation, also known as fraud or deceit, is committed when a potential defendant knowingly makes a false material statement to the potential plaintiff with the intent that the plaintiff rely on that false information. The plaintiff can then recover if she can demonstrate reliance on the false claim and damages suffered as a result.168 Misrepresentation is an attractive tort solution to the harm of payday lending because it can apply specifically to pecuniary damages. The primary challenge for a plaintiff using this tort will be to demonstrate that the payday loan supplier made a false material statement. In the easiest cases, the loan provider will have lied about the interest rate, leading the plaintiff to agree to a loan that she might have otherwise rejected. In most cases, however, such a clear misrepresentation will not have occurred. The lender might have only been silent as to the interest rate or other terms of the loan. While the actual loan document will contain the necessary information, someone in the borrower’s situation might not have the financial literacy or desire to read the fine print. If this is the case, the lender’s failure to openly disclose the terms of the loan could be seen as contributing to the borrower’s decision to take the loan. In many states, an omission of pertinent information qualifies as misrepresentation. For example, in the District of Columbia, plaintiffs can show the defendant made a false statement or an omission of fact to establish a misrepresentation claim.169 Courts might be receptive to applying negligent misrepresentation to payday lending. Consider Arthur Jackson, the warehouse worker who took out a $300 loan to supplement his income and help his daughter open her small business, only to be saddled with debt as a result of frequent rollovers on his original loan. In response to Arthur’s initial inquiry about obtaining a loan, agents of Advance America failed to tell him about how the terms would be modified should he need to roll the loan over. Given the frequency with which borrowers are forced to roll over their loans, a case could be made that Arthur’s lender engaged in misrepresentation by not fully and openly disclosing the terms of the loan. Similarly, Sandra Harris, the accounting technician who now owes thousands of dollars in back taxes as a result of payday loans, might be able to bring a suit of misrepresentation against the lenders who failed to disclose to her the potential dangers that could ensue as a result of her loan renewals. Product Liability Under existing law, at least two kinds of products liability claims are available against manufacturers and vendors: negligence and strict liability. The former lets plaintiffs recover where their cases meet the ordinary standards of negligence (i.e. 29 Courts might be receptive to applying negligent misrepresentation to payday lending. Although the odds might seem stacked against the plaintiff due to the restrictive definition of “products,” it would certainly not be foreign to the common law tradition for judges to expand the meaning of a legal term to reflect the changing social trend and achieve a just outcome. where the defendant knew or should have known that the product was dangerous and still proceeded to sell it to the plaintiff, thereby damaging her).170 In the latter case, while plaintiffs need not show negligence they still must show that the product was defective, and that the defendant was a “merchant.” However, tort law today does not recognize service providers as “merchants,” so strict liability is not applicable.171 Additionally, the term “products,” as it is used in both types A borrower’s story: Stevie is a Baptist minister in Kansas City. When his father became terminally ill he began working less to care for him. Stevie and his wife eventually fell behind on mortgage payments, even after withdrawing from her retirement account to attempt to keep up. Stevie took out a $500 payday loan and expected to pay it back in two weeks. Within four months the amount he owed had grown from $500 to $1250. He says he was so alarmed that he “scraped together” the money and paid it off, but Stevie joined with other religious leaders in the area to push for an end to what he calls “a debt trap” and “a nightmare.” “Many consumers, like my wife and I, aren’t stupid,” he says. “We need no pity.” Adapted from http://www.piconetwork.org/newsmedia/coverage/2009/0203, https:// www.youtube.cofm/watch?v=Dv7CaPsZxqQ 30 of liability claims does not include financial “products,” but only physical products.172 Finally, the damages recoverable are limited to physical damages to the person or property under both claims.173 Given these legal constraints, the first hurdle for any plaintiff who seeks a tort remedy in products liability is to show that payday loans are “products.” Although the odds might seem stacked against the plaintiff due to the restrictive definition of “products,” it would certainly not be foreign to the common law tradition for judges to expand the meaning of a legal term to reflect the changing social trend and achieve a just outcome.174 The case of the payday loan might well be such an exceptional occasion. Because consumers suffer in the same way from defective nonphysical products as they do from defective physical products, restricting remedies to claims for defective physical products seems unjust. Once payday loans are recognized as products, the loan providers will likely be considered as commercial sellers, paving the way for strict liability. Under this theory, a plaintiff only has to prove damages and product deficiency. If economic damages are recognized, the damages will consist of the plaintiff’s economic loss. The deficiency is likely to be found in the exorbitant interest rate, which was probably unclear to the consumer at first glance given the way payday loans are marketed. Abnormally Dangerous Lending: A New Tort? While courts could possibly be persuaded to expand existing tort liabilities to account for payday lending practices, a more direct tort solution to the problem would be the creation of a new tort cause of action. Based on evidence of the deceptive and damaging practices provided earlier in this white paper, we propose the new tort of abnormally dangerous lending. Under this new legal regime, a borrower could present the story of the lending practices used against him and the resultant impact to a neutral fact finder. After receiving the lender’s perspective of the events, the neutral body would decide if the behavior was abnormally dangerous or usurious. If so, the lender would be entitled to recover the loan principal and nothing more from the defaulted borrower, releasing that harmed borrower from a possible debt spiral. Since lenders have regularly sidestepped regulations, we would intentionally give the fact finder wide discretion to decide whether the lender engaged in lending that meets a standard of unreasonably dangerous or usurious practices. That said, we would propose that the following considerations factor into the final decision: whether the borrower was made aware of the risk involved in taking and renewing the loan; how the lender marketed the loan both at the point of sale and, if applicable, in the community at large; and whether the borrower’s condition has been significantly worsened by the loan. With these general factors— as opposed to specific and more avoidable triggers for liability— guiding the neutral group’s inquiry, payday lenders will not be able to benefit from the inherently dangerous lending currently being practiced. While the exact details of how this abnormally dangerous lending tort would be adjudicated are not a t t e m p t e d i n t h i s p a p e r, w e nevertheless hope to have demonstrated that such an expansion of the tort frontier might be warranted to curb a practice currently harming millions of Americans. CONCLUSION Predatory lending is a problem, and payday loans are a type of predatory lending that is especially troublesome today. Predatory lending is deeply rooted in our history, and although the situation of the borrower has changed throughout history, predatory lending remains a problem. The same is true of payday loans. Those who use payday loans have not chosen to engage in a known risk, but rather have been targeted, bamboozled, and placed into an unending and inescapable debtor's cycle. The Predatory Lending Group at Harvard Law School identified practical policy solutions, a current tort solution, and a newly created tort to free the prey from their predators. 31 Based on evidence of the deceptive and damaging practices provided earlier in this white paper, we propose the new tort of abnormally dangerous lending. After the presentation on November 20, 2013, members of Section Six voted on every policy and tort solution proposed by this white paper. Each one of these proposed solutions account for a multitude of factors, and could help solve the problems borrowers face with payday loans. For policy solutions, fifty-five members of the class voted to replace the balloon payment structure of payday loans with an amortized structure, and fifty-three members voted to cap the interest rates or amount borrowers could receive in a loan. For tort solutions, forty-four members of the class voted for utilizing the doctrine of misrepresentation. Finally, fifty-four members of the class voted for the newly created "abnormally dangerous credit marketing tort." Each one of these proposed solutions account for a multitude of factors, and could help solve the problems borrowers face with payday loans. 32 REFERENCES 1 PayDay Loan Consumer Information, CONSUMER FEDERATION OF AMERICA, http://www.paydayloaninfo.org/facts (last visited Nov. 24, 2013). 2 Id. 3 Paige Marta Skiba and Jeremy Tobacman, Do Payday Loans Cause Bankruptcy?, VANDERBILT LAW AND ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NO. 11-13 21, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1266215. 4 Hayley Peterson, 6 Outrageous Facts That Show How Payday Lenders Screw Consumers, BUSINESS INSIDER (Oct. 25, 2013), http://www.businessinsider.com/outrageous-facts-about-payday-loans-2013-10; Victims of Payday Lending: Sandra Harris, CENTER FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, http://www.responsiblelending.org/payday-lending/ tools-resources/victims-2.html (last visited Nov. 22, 2013); Victims of Payday Lending: Arthur Jackson, CENTER FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, http://www.responsiblelending.org/payday-lending/tools-resources/victims-4.html (last visited Nov. 22, 2013). 5 Victims of Payday Lending: Sandra Harris, CENTER FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, http:// www.responsiblelending.org/payday-lending/tools-resources/victims-4.html (last visited Nov. 22, 2013). 6 About Us, ADVANCE AMERICA, https://www.advanceamerica.net/about-us (last visited Nov. 24, 2013). 7 About Cash Advances, ADVANCE AMERICA, https://www.advanceamerica.net/about-us/about-cash-advances (last visited Nov. 24, 2013). 8 Id. 9 John P. Caskey, Payday Lending: New Research and the Big Question 1 (Fed. Reserve Bank of Phila., Working Paper No. 10-32, 2010), available at http://www.phil.frb.org/research-and-data/publications/working-papers/2010/ wp10-32.pdf. 10 Nick Bourke et al., PAYDAY LENDING IN AMERICA: WHO BORROWS, WHERE THEY BORROW AND WHY, THE PEW CHARITABLE TRUSTS REPORT 4 (2012) available at http://www.pewtrusts.org/our_work_report_detail.aspx? id=85899406010. 11 See Niraj Chokshi, Paydayloans suck up billions in fees in states where they’re unregulated, GOVBEAT (Sept. 11, 2013, 8:45am), http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/govbeat/wp/2013/09/11/payday-loans-still-suck-up-billionsin-fees-in-states-where-theyre-unregulated/; N.Y. Times Editorial Board, Progress on Predatory Lending, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 15, 2013, http://www.nytimes.com/2013/09/16/opinion/progress-on-predatory-lending.html. 12 GARY RIVLIN, BROKE, USA: FROM PAWNSHOPS TO POVERTY, INC. 32-33 (HarperCollins, 2010). (Industry consultants advise payday lenders in marketing approaches to encourage repeat borrowing claiming that such loyal customers can pay from $2,000-$4,000 per year in fees). 13 Michael A. Stegman, Payday Lending, 21 J. Econ. Perspectives 169-71 (2007).See also Rivlin, supra note 12. 14 Legal Status of Payday Loans by State, CONSUMER FEDERATION OF AMERICA, http://www.paydayloaninfo.org/ state-information (last visited Nov. 24, 2013).See also CFBP Examines Payday Lending, CONSUMER FINANCIAL PROTECTION BUREAU, http://www.consumerfinance.gov/newsroom/consumer-financial-protection-bureauexamines-payday-lending/ (last visited Nov. 24, 2013). 15 Rates, WESTERN SKY FINANCIAL, http://www.westernsky.com/General/Rates.aspx (last visited Nov. 24, 2013). 33 16 For biblical references see, e.g., Leviticus 25:36-37, Exodus 22:24, and Deuteronomy 23:20-21. The Code of Hammurabi specifically mentions usury; both ancient Roman and Greek law prohibited usury. Medieval canon law went further and prohibited interest altogether, although avoidance techniques were abundant. James M. Ackerman, Interest Rates and the Law: A History of Usury, 1981 ARIZ. ST. L.J. 61, 66-70 (1981). Famous literary references include Dante's Divine Comedy and Shakespeare's Merchant of Venice, both demonizing and abhorring usury. However, changing attitudes and outright attacks against usury statutes appeared in the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries in the works of liberal philosophers, most notably John Locke and Jeremy Bentham. Id. at 82-83. In America, early colonial usury laws were modeled after the English Statute of Anne which capped interest at 5% (Act to Reduce Rate of Interest, 13 Anne, c. 15 (1713)), but were later repealed or severely modified in many states under the influence of the laissez-faire philosophy. Id. at 85-87. Further to that, right from the get-go the history of American usury law has been a history of exceptions. By the 1950s, these exceptions threatened to overwhelm the rule. Although nearly all states retained a general usury limit, regulation was increasingly provided by a bewildering and disorganized array of statutory exceptions. Id. at 94 17 Rebekah Coleman, Evolution of the Payday Lending War, LOANS.ORG, http://loans.org/payday/articles/evolutioncash-advance-lending-war (last visited Nov. 24, 2013) 18 Robert Mayer, Loan Sharks, Interest-Rate Caps, and Deregulation, 69 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 807, 811, 836 (2012). 19 ROBERT MAYER, QUICK CASH: THE STORY OF THE LOAN SHARK 15 (2010). 20 See generally MAYER, supra note 18. 21 Mayer, supra note 18, at 812. 22 See Mark H. Haller and John V. Alviti, Loansharking in American Cities: Historical Analysis of a Marginal Enterprise, 21 AM. J. LEG. HIST. 125, 127 (1977) (noting that it was “frowned upon consumer borrowing as a sign of poor budget management and moral weakness on the part of the borrower”). 23 See generally Elizabeth Anderson, Experts, Ideas, and Policy Change: The Russell Sage Foundation and Small Loan Reform, 1909–1941, 37 THEORY & SOC’Y 271 (2008). 24 See Bruce G. Carruthers et al., Bringing "honest capital" to poor borrowers: The passage of the uniform small loan law, 1907-1930 (Economic Growth Center, Discussion Paper No. 971, 2009) (noting that "[i]nterest rates of 3.5 percent per month sounded bizarre to many at the time, and defending it on some occasions led to the charge that the Foundation was simply a front for high-rate lenders." and that "[i]n several state legislatures RSF was asked to explain its connection to lender’s organizations; was it simply an industry group? "). 25 See id. 26 The adoption of USLA was a long process, but ultimately all states except Arkansas passed a version of it, albeit not always uniform. The interest rate was set at 18-42% annually, which was estimated as the minimal rate allowing operation at a profitable level. See supra note 24. 27. See Turner v. E-Z Check Cashing of Cookeville, TN, Inc., 35 F. Supp. 2d 1042, 1047 (M.D. Tenn. 1999) (“It has been held that payday loans fall under the disclosure provisions of the TILA”). 28 Mayer, supra note 18, at 836. 29 Ackerman, 30 supra note 16, at 93. 439 U.S. 299 (1978). 31 Christopher L. Peterson, Truth, Understanding, and High-Cost Consumer Credit: The Historical Context of the Truth in Lending Act, 55 FLA. L. REV. 807, 873 (2003). (“Most notably, this was the case in South Dakota, South Carolina, Utah, and Delaware, which removed all interest rate caps”). 32 Pub. L. No. 96–221. 34 33 Ronald J. Mann & Jim Hawkins, Just Until Payday, 54 UCLA L. REV. 855, 867 (2007). 34 Id at 866, 868 (hypothesizing that there is a chronic violation of applicable laws governing usury, as well as cheating). 35 See Id at 874-880 (dividing the states into categories of "explicit toleration," "underenforced prohibition," and "true prohibition"). 36 12 U.S.C. § 5517(o). 37 See 10 U.S.C. § 987. 38 Id. 39 See 10 U.S.C. § 934. 40 Jessica Silver-Greenberg & Peter Eavis, Service Members Left Vulnerable to Payday Loans, DEALBOOK (Nov. 21, 2013, 8:48 PM), http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2013/11/21/service-members-left-vulnerable-to-payday-loans/? _r=1. 41 Caskey, supra note 9. 42 Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, Payday Loans and Deposit Advance Products: A White Paper of Initial Data Findings 6 (2013), available at http://files.consumerfinance.gov/f/201304_cfpb_payday-dap-whitepaper.pdf. 43 See id. at 9. 44 See, HOW BORROWERS CHOOSE AND REPAY PAYDAY LOANS, THE PEW CHARITABLE TRUSTS REPORT 4 (2013) available at http://www.pewstates.org/research/reports/how-borrowers-choose-and-repay-paydayloans-85899452131. (“In deciding whether to borrow from a payday lender, more than 3 in 4 borrowers rely on lenders to provide accurate information about the product, and lenders describe loans as ‘safe,’ ‘a sensible financial choice,’ and ‘the best alternative to meet their current needs’ for a ‘one-time fixed fee.’”). See also ROB LEVY & JOSHUA SLEDGE, CTR. FOR FIN. SERVS. INNOVATION, A COMPLEX PORTRAIT: AN EXAMINATION OF SMALL-DOLLAR CREDIT CONSUMERS 15 (2012). See generally Ian Ayres & Alan Schwartz, The No Reading Problem in Consumer Contract Law, STANFORD L. REV. (forthcoming 2013). 45 See Truth in Lending Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1601-1667f (2010). 46 Gregory Elliehausen & Edward Lawrence, Payday Advance Credit in America: An Analysis of Customer Demand (Credit Research Ctr., Monograph No. 35, 2001), available at http://faculty.msb.edu/prog/CRC/pdf/Mono35.PDF. 47 RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW § 1.1 at 10 (4th ed. 1992). 48 See id. § 1.2 at 13. Note that efficiency here refers to Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, which means only that overall social value, or wealth, is maximized. The question of whether the transaction’s participants or third parties benefit individually does not figure into Kaldor-Hicks efficiency. 49 See, e.g., Dean Karlan & Jonathan Zinman, Op-Ed., In Defense of Usury, WALL ST. J., Nov. 1, 2007, http:// online.wsj.com/article/SB119388104410378595.html. 50 Daniel P. Morgan & Michael R. Strain, Payday Holiday: How Households Fare after Payday Credit Bans 3 (Fed. Reserve Bank of N.Y., Staff Report No. 309, 2008), available at http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/ staff_reports/sr309.pdf. 51 See Mark Flannery & Katherine Samolyk, Payday Lending: Do the Costs Justify the Price? (FDIC, Working Paper No. 2005-09, 2005), available at http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/cfr/2005/wp2005/ CFRWP_2005-09_Flannery_Samolyk.pdf. 35 52 As Joseph Stiglitz, who won the Nobel Prize in Economics for his work on imperfect information, has written, “[t]he standard theorems that underlie the presumption that markets are efficient are no longer valid once we take into account the fact that information is costly and imperfect. . . . The fact that markets with imperfect information do not work perfectly provides a rationale for potential government actions.” Joseph E. Stiglitz, Information, LIBRARY OF ECONOMICS AND LIBERTY, http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/Information.html (last visited Nov. 23, 2013). 53 See infra The Psychology of Payday Lending at 24. 54 Id. 55 See infra Examining the External Situation at 19. 56 See LEVY & SLEDGE, supra at 44; PEW, supra at 44. 57 See Michael Bertics, Note, Fixing Payday Lending: The Potential of Greater Bank Involvement, 9 N.C. BANKING INST. J. 133, 142 (2005) (arguing that imperfect information, among other factors, produces “tacit collusion” among payday lenders, with the result that “monopolists earn excess return on capital, economic rent, and the consumer is worse off than if the market functioned perfectly”). 58 Tyler Cowen, Public Goods and Externalities, LIBRARY OF ECONOMICS AND LIBERTY, http://www.econlib.org/ library/Enc1/PublicGoodsandExternalities.html (last visited Nov. 23, 2013). 59 See WARD FARNSWORTH, THE LEGAL ANALYST 47-56 (2007). 60 Escola v. Coca Cola Bottling Co. of Fresno, 150 P.2d 436, 441 (1944). 61 Payday Lending in America: Who Borrows, Where They Borrow, and Why, PEW CHARITABLE TRUSTS 1, 4–5, (July 2012), http://www.pewtrusts.org/uploadedFiles/wwwpewtrustsorg/Reports/Safe_Small_Dollar_Loans/ LOANS_Payday%20Lending%20Report%20Final_web.pdf. 62 Id. at 4. 63 Id. at 4. 64 Id. at 8. 65 Id. at 10-11. 66 Nathalie Martin and Ernesto Longa, High-Interest Loans and Class: Do Payday and Title Loans Really Serve the Middle Class?, 24 LOYOLA CONSUMER L. REV. 524, 524 (2012). 67 Michael A. Stegman, Payday Lending, 21 J. ECON. PERS. 169, 170 (2007). 68 Nathalie Martin, 1,000% Interest — Good While Supplies Last: A Study of Payday Loan Practices and Solutions, 52 ARIZ. L. REV. 1, 10 (2010). 69 Id. at 10-11. 70 Payday Lending in America: Policy Solutions, PEW CHARITABLE TRUSTS (Oct. 2013), http://www.pewstates.org/ research/reports/payday-lending-in-america-policy-solutions-85899513326. 71 Wei Li et al., Predatory Profiling: The Role of Race and Ethnicity in the Location of Payday Lenders in California, CENTER FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING (Mar. 26, 2009), 3, http://www.responsiblelending.org/california/ ca-payday/research-analysis/predatory-profiling.html. 72 Jean Ann Fox, The Military Lending Act Five Years Later, CONSUMER FED’N OF AM. (May 29, 2012), 31, http:// www.consumerfed.org/pdfs/Studies.MilitaryLendingAct.5.29.12.pdf. 36 73See Steve Hawkes, Martin Lewis: Payday Lenders Target Children’s TV to ‘Groom’ Next Generation of Borrowers, THE TELEGRAPH (Nov. 5, 2013, 11:02 AM), http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/politics/10427061/Martin-Lewispayday-lenders-target-childrens-TV-to-groom-next-generation-of-borrowers.html. 74See Jennifer E. Glick, Immigration and Changing Patterns of Extended Family Household Structure in the United States, 79 J. MARRIAGE & FAM. 177, 177 (1997). 75 Payday Lending in America, supra note 62, at 16. 76See 77 ROBERT D. PUTNAM, BOWLING ALONE: THE COLLAPSE AND REVIVAL OF AMERICAN COMMUNITY 19 (2000). Id. at 321. 78 ROBERT D. MANNING, CREDIT CARD NATION: THE CONSEQUENCES OF AMERICA’S ADDICTION TO CREDIT 3 (2000). 79 Matthew J. Bernthal et al., Credit Cards as Lifestyle Facilitators, 32 J. CONSUMER RES. 130, 131 (2005). 80 Payday Lending in America, supra note 62, at 16. 81 Id. at 5. 82 See, e.g., Alice Gallmeyer and Wade T. Roberts, Payday Lenders and Economically Distressed Communities, 46 SOCIAL SCI. J. 521, 522 (2009). 83 Gregory Elliehausen, An Analysis of Consumers’ Use of Payday Loans, 1 GEO. WASH. U. SCH. OF BUS. FIN. SERVICES RES. PROGRAM 41 (2009), http://www.approvedcashadvance.com/docs/GWUAnalysis_01-2009.pdf. 84 Id. at 32. 85 Id. at 33. 86 GALLMEYER & ROBERTS, supra note 82, at 522. 87 Fast Facts: Payday Loans, CENTER FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, http://www.responsiblelending.org/paydaylending/tools-resources/fast-facts.html (last visited Nov. 11, 2013). 88 Mark Flannery and Katherine Samolyk, Payday Lending: Do the Costs Justify the Price?,12 (June 23, 2005), http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/cfr/2005/wp2005/CFRWP_2005-09_Flannery_Samolyk.pdf. 89 Id. at 12, 12-19. 90 Taiki Takahashi et al., Cultural Neuroeconomics of Intertemporal Choice, 30 NEUROENDOCRINOLOGY LETTERS 185, 185-191 (2009). Anuj K. Shah et al., Some Consequences of Having Too Little, 338 SCIENCE 682, 682–85 (2012). 91 92 Y. Yang & A. Raine, Prefrontal Structural and Functional Brain Imaging Findings in Antisocial, Violent, and Psychopathic Individuals: A Meta-Analysis, 174 PSYCHIATRY RES. 81, 81–88 (2009). 93 Bruce S. McEwen & John H. Morrison, The Brain on Stress: Vulnerability and Plasticity of the Prefrontal Cortex over the Life Course. 79 NEURON 16, 16–29 (2013). 94 J. M. Soares et al., Stress-induced Changes in Human Decision-Making are Reversible, 2 TRANSLATIONAL PSYCHIATRY 131 (2012). 95 Marianne Bertrand et al., Behavioral Economics and Marketing in Aid of Decision Making Among the Poor, 25 JOURNAL OF PUBLIC POLICY AND MARKETING 8, 11 (2006). 37 96 Id. at 8. 97 FED. DEP’T INS. CORP., 2011 FDIC NATIONAL SURVEY OF UNBANKED AND UNDERBANKED HOUSEHOLDS (2012). 98 BERTRANDT ET AL. supra note 99, at 12. 99 Id. 100 Id. at 11. 101 Tom R. Tyler, Multiculturalism and the Willingness of Citizens to Defer to Law and to Legal Authorities, 25 LAW & SOCIAL INQUIRY 983, 991 (2000). 102 Tagline from a payday loan lender, ezmoneypaydayloans.com 103 Russell Revlin, Cognition: Theory and Practice 352 (2013). 104 Craig R. Fox & Amos Tversky, Ambiguity Aversion and Comparative Ignorance, Q. J. ECON. 585, 587 (1995) 105 Jon D. Hanson & Douglas A. Kysar, Taking Behavioralism Seriously: The Problem of Market Manipulation, 74 N.Y.U. L. REV. 630, 735 (1999). 106 Id. at 654 107 Id. at 658 108 Late fees are a common example of this phenomenon. Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Contract: Law, Economics, and Psychology in Consumer Markets, 3 (2012) 109 Pam Fessler, I Applied For An Online Payday Loan. Here’s What Happened Next, NAT’L PUBLIC RADIO (Nov. 6, 2013, 3:03 AM), http://www.npr.org/blogs/money/2013/11/06/242351534/i-applied-for-an-online-payday-loanheres-what-happened-next. 110 Marianne Bertrand et al., Behavioral Economics and Marketing in Aid of Decision Making Among the Poor, 25 J. PU. POL’Y & MARKETING 8, 8 (2006). 111 Hayley Peterson, 6 Outrageous Facts That Show How Payday Lenders Screw Consumers, BUS. INSIDER (Oct. 25, 2013), http://www.businessinsider.com/outrageous-facts-about-payday-loans-2013-10. 112 Victims of Payday Lending: Sandra Harris, CENTER FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, http:// www.responsiblelending.org/payday-lending/tools-resources/victims-2.html (last visited Nov. 12, 2013). 113 Victims of Payday Lending: Arthur Jackson, CENTER FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING, http:// www.responsiblelending.org/payday-lending/tools-resources/victims-4.html (last visited Nov. 12, 2013). 114 Victims of Payday Lending: Sandra Harris, supra note 117. 115Ace Cash Express, Loans Up to $1,000 in Minutes, YOUTUBE (Nov. 22, 2013), http://www.youtube.com/ watch?v=gvAocaVnY9k. 116 MoneyMutual, Designed With You In Mind, YOUTUBE (Nov. 22, 2013), http://www.youtube.com/watch? v=oTuHQY-07hA. 117 Editorial Board, Cracking Down on Predatory Payday Lenders, N.Y. TIMES (Aug. 29, 2013), http:// www.nytimes.com/2013/08/30/opinion/cracking-down-on-predatory-payday-lenders.html?_r=0. 118 Jennifer Bjorhus, Fight Against Illegal Payday Loans Turns to Banks, STAR TRIBUNE (Nov. 9, 2013), http:// www.startribune.com/business/231213561.html?page=1&c=y. 38 119 Herb Weisbaum, Have a Problem with a Payday Loan? The Feds Want Your Complaint, TODAY MONEY (Nov. 8, 2013), http://www.today.com/money/have-problem-payday-loan-feds-want-your-complaint-8C11554115. 120 See, e.g., Tim Worstall, Why Payday Loans Are So Expensive, FORBES (Dec. 20, 2011), http://www.forbes.com/ sites/timworstall/2011/12/20/why-payday-loans-are-so-expensive/. 121 Megan McArdle, Can Credit Unions Replace 'Predatory' Lending?, THE ATLANTIC (Jan. 6, 2012, 2:13 PM), http://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2012/01/can-credit-unions-replace-predatory-lending/251004/. 122 Mark Flannery and Katherine Samolyk, Payday Lending: Do the Costs Justify the Price?, FED. DEPOSIT INS. CORP. (June 2005), http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/cfr/2005/wp2005/cfrwp_2005-09_flannery_samolyk.pdf. 123 John Leland, Nonprofit Payday Loans? Yes, to Mixed Reviews, N.Y. TIMES, (Aug. 28, 2007), http:// www.nytimes.com/2007/08/28/us/28payday.html. 124 Megan McArdle, On Poverty, Interest Rates, and Payday Loans, THE ATLANTIC (Nov. 18, 2009), http:// www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2009/11/on-poverty-interest-rates-and-payday-loans/30431/. 125 Understanding Loans; Five Loans to Avoid, NEW YORK CITY DEPT. OF CONSUMER AFFAIRS (last visited Nov. 9, 2013), http://www.nyc.gov/html/ofe/html/help/avoid.shtml; Car Title Lending: Driving Borrowers to Financial Ruin, CENTER FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING (Nov. 9, 2013), http://www.responsiblelending.org/other-consumerloans/car-title-loans/research-analysis/car-title-lending-driving-borrowers-to-financial-ruin.html. 126 Flannery and Samolyk, supra note 122. 127 T.W. Farnam, Payday Lenders Up Their Contributions To Candidates, WASH. POST (Apr. 18, 2012), http:// www.washingtonpost.com/politics/payday-lenders-up-their-contributions-to-candidates/2012/04/18/ gIQAziioRT_story.html. 128 Payday Lenders Pay More, CITIZENS FOR RESPONSIBILITY AND ETHICS IN WASHINGTON (Mar. 15, 2011), http:// www.scribd.com/doc/50785926/CREW-Payday-Lenders-Report-2011. 129 Loan-Shark-Financed Campaigns Threaten Payday-Loan Reform, TEXANS FOR PUBLIC JUSTICE (Mar. 2011), http://info.tpj.org/reports/pdf/PaydayReport.mar2011.pdf. 130 Forrest Wilder, A Last-Ditch Effort to Rein in Payday Loans, TEX. OBSERVER (May 8, 2013), http:// www.texasobserver.org/a-last-ditch-effort-to-rein-in-payday-loans/ 131 See, e.g., Lawrence Meyers, Payday Loan ‘Cycle of Debt’ is a False Narrative, DALLAS MORNING NEWS (Apr. 10, 2013), http://www.dallasnews.com/opinion/latest-columns/20130410-lawrence-meyers-payday-loan-cycle-ofdebt-is-a-false-narrative.ece. 132 Direct Deposit Advance Service Agreement and Product Guide, WELLS FARGO (Apr. 1, 2013), https:// www.wellsfargo.com/assets/pdf/personal/checking/direct-deposit-advance/termsandconditions_english.pdf. 133 Zach Carter, In Stealth Lobbying Move, Wall Street Coordinates With Check-Cashers, Payday Lenders To Gut CFPB, HUFFINGTON POST (May 25, 2011), http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2011/03/01/cfpb-lobbying-checkcashers-payday-lenders_n_829838.html. 134 Sophia Pearson, BMO Harris Bank Among Companies Sued Over Payday Loans, BLOOMBERG BUSINESSWEEK (Oct. 12, 2013), http://www.businessweek.com/news/2013-10-11/bmo-harris-bank-among-companies-sued-overpayday-loans-1. 135 Payday Lending in America: Report 2: How Borrowers Choose and Repay Payday Loans, PEW CHARITABLE TRUSTS 35 (Feb. 2013), http://www.pewstates.org/uploadedFiles/PCS_Assets/2013/ Pew_Choosing_Borrowing_Payday_Feb2013.pdf. 136 Jessica Silver-Greenberg, Major Banks Aid in Payday Loans Banned by States, N.Y. TIMES (Feb. 23, 2013), http://www.nytimes.com/2013/02/24/business/major-banks-aid-in-payday-loans-banned-by-states.html. 39 137 Lauren K. Saunders, Leah A. Plunkett, and Carolyn Carter, Stopping the Payday Loan Trap: Alternatives that Work, Ones that Don’t, NAT’L CONSUMER LAW CTR. (June 2010), http://www.nclc.org/images/pdf/ high_cost_small_loans/payday_loans/report-stopping-payday-trap.pdf 138 For a brief history of payday lending to military personnel, see Military and Payday, CTR. FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING (Nov. 22, 2010), http://www.responsiblelending.org/payday-lending/policy-legislation/congress/militaryand-payday.html 139 Implementation of Limitations on Terms of Consumer Credit Extended to Service Members and Dependents, CTR. (Feb. 25, 2008), http://www.responsiblelending.org/payday-lending/policy-legislation/ congress/MIL_DOD_08_MLA_CommentsFinal-2_23.pdf;Limitations on Terms of Consumer Credit Extended to Service Members and Dependents, CTR. FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING (Aug. 1, 2013), http:// www.responsiblelending.org/payday-lending/policy-legislation/regulators/ CFA_Comments_DoD_ANPR_13_8_1.pdf. FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING 140 Impact of Overdraft Programs on Consumers, CTR. FOR RESPONSIBLE LENDING (June 29, 2012), http:// www.responsiblelending.org/overdraft-loans/policy-legislation/regulators/Overdraft-Comment-by-CRL-CFA-andNCLC-Docket-No-CFPB-2012-0007.pdf. 141 Tyler Evilsizer, Lenders Couldn’t Buy Laws, NAT’L INST. www.followthemoney.org/press/Reports/Payday.pdf. ON MONEY IN STATE POLITICS (Aug. 18, 2009), http:// 142 Ohio Issues Report, OFFICE OF THE OHIO SEC’Y OF STATE 17 (2008), http://www.sos.state.oh.us/sos/upload/ publications/election/Issues_08.pdf. 143 Paul Kiel, The Payday Playbook: How High Cost Lenders Fight to Stay Legal, PRO PUBLICA (Aug. 2, 2013), http://www.propublica.org/article/how-high-cost-lenders-fight-to-stay-legal. 144 Payday Lenders in Arkansas: Consumers Win as Predatory Industry Leaves Arkansas for Good, ARKANSANS AGAINST ABUSIVE PAYDAY LENDING (Aug. 2009), http://www.paydayloaninfo.org/elements/ www.paydayloaninfo.org/File/aaapl_08_09_study%281%29.pdf. 145 Tyler Evilsizer, supra note 140. 146 TILA treats payday loans like most any other form of closed-end credit—the FDIC applies the disclosure requirements of its Regulation Z. See Truth in Lending Act, FDIC COMPLIANCE MANUAL (June 2013), available at http://www.fdic.gov/regulations/compliance/manual/pdf/V-1.1.pdf. 147 The State of Indiana has prepared a useful set of examples of the types of disclosures that TILA requires be provided to payday loan customers. Truth in Lending Disclosure Examples: Closed-End Disclosures. IND. DEP’T OF FIN. INST…available at http://www.in.gov/dfi/2583.htm. 148 Here, we might envision lenders providing potential customers with something like a six-month-long analysis of what signing the loan would mean for that customer. That is, the document given to the customer would detail principal payments and finance charges, vis-à-vis the customer’s expected earnings over that interval and other such relevant information over that same time period. 149 Payday Loan Reform Act of 2009, H.R. 1214, 111th Cong. § 2 (2009), available at https://www.govtrack.us/ congress/bills/111/hr1214/text. 150 Ian Ayers & Alan Schwartz, The No Reading Problem in Consumer Contract Law, STAN. L. REV. (forthcoming 2013), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2341840. 151 Paige Marta Skiba & Jeremy Tobacman, Payday Loans, Uncertainty and Discounting: Explaining Patterns of Borrowing, Repayment and Default, FDIC (November 19, 2007), http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/cfr/2008/jan/ CFR_SS_2008Tobacman1.pdf. 152 Of course, this would put payday loans in competition with other collateralized loans; the resulting implications might ultimately make this solution less feasible than other alternatives. 40 153 Bob Sullivan, Pay $2,140 to borrow $950? That’s how car title loans work, NBC NEWS (Mar. 5, 2013, 2:49 PM), http://www.nbcnews.com/technology/pay-2-140-borrow-950-thats-how-car-title-loans-1C8703205. 154 Colin Morgan-Cross & Marieka Klawitter, Effects of State Payday Loan Price Caps & Regulation, UNIVERSITY (Dec. 2, 2011), http://depts.washington.edu/wcpc/sites/default/files/papers/Payday%20Lending %20Brief.pdf. OF WASHINGTON 4 155 Id., at 1. 156 Payday Lending in America: Policy Solutions, PEW CHARITABLE TRUSTS (Oct. 30, 2013), http:// www.pewstates.org/research/reports/payday-lending-in-america-policy-solutions-85899513326?p=3. 157 Colin Morgan-Cross & Marieka Klawitter, supra note 153, at 5. 158 SBA Loan Programs, U.S. SMALL BUS. ADMIN., http://www.sba.gov/content/microloan-program (last accessed Nov. 24, 2013). 159 Shalia Dewan, Microcredit for Americans, N.Y. TIMES (Oct. 28, 2013), http://www.nytimes.com/2013/10/29/ business/microcredit-for-americans.html. 160 Neil MacFarquhar, Banks Making Big Profits from Tiny Loans, N.Y. TIMES (Apr. 13, 2013), http:// www.nytimes.com/2010/04/14/world/14microfinance.html?pagewanted=all. 161 See National Conference of State Legislatures: Payday Lending Statutes, available at http://www.ncsl.org/ research/financial-services-and-commerce/payday-lending-state-statutes.aspx. 162 Id. 163 Id. 164 DODD-FRANK WALL STREET REFORM AND CONSUMER PROTECTION ACT, 124 Stat 1376.§ 1202-1209. 165 For a recent enforcement action by the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, see Jim Puzzanghera, Payday Lender Fined by Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, L.A. TIMES, Nov. 20, 2013. 166 Cappello & Noel, LLP, What is Lender Liability? FINDLAW (2008). 167 John R. Ruhl, 10 Commandments for Avoiding Lender Liability, RYAN SWANSON & CLEVELAND, PPLC. 168 Negligent misrepresentation provides a slightly lower bar for recovery of damages. The elements of a negligent misrepresentation tort are 1) misrepresentation by a defendant in a business or professional capacity 2) a breach of duty toward the plaintiff 3) a justifiable reliance by the plaintiff on the false statement and 4) damages. 169 See Doe v. District of Columbia, No. 05-1060, 2013 WL 3957448, at *17-18 (D. D.C. Aug. 1, 2013) (To establish a claim for negligent misrepresentation under District of Columbia law, a plaintiff must show that the defendant made a false statement or omission of a fact). 170 RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 399 (1965). 171 Id., at § 402A. 172 Id. 173 Id., § 399, § 402A; 12 AM. JUR. TRIALS 1 § 41 (Originally published in 1966). 174 See, e.g., Vosburg v. Putney, 50 N.W. 403 (1891); Kerans v. Porter Paint Co., Inc., 656 F. Supp. 267 (S.D. Ohio 1987). 41