A survey of the approaches and methods used to

Transcription

A survey of the approaches and methods used to
A survey of the approaches and
methods used to assess the
economic effects of a
Competition Authority’s work
Uppdragsforskningsrapport 2012:1
En rapport skriven av
Stephen Davies
på uppdrag av Konkurrensverket
Uppdragsforskningsrapport 2012:1
Stephen Davies
ISSN-nr 1401-8438
Konkurrensverket, Stockholm 2012
Foto: Matton Images
Förord
I Konkurrensverkets uppdrag ingår att främja forskning på konkurrens- och
upphandlingsområdet.
Konkurrensverket har gett professor Stephen Davies vid University of East Anglia,
i uppdrag att redovisa för- och nackdelar med olika metoder och angreppssätt för
att utvärdera effekterna av konkurrensmyndigheters arbete.
Till projektet har knutits en referensgrupp. Den har bestått av Sten Nyberg
(Stockholms universitet) samt Arvid Fredenberg, Lena Fredriksson och Erik
Hegelund från Konkurrensverket.
Det är författaren som svarar för alla slutsatser och bedömningar i rapporten.
Stockholm, maj 2012
Dan Sjöblom
Generaldirektör
Contents
Sammanfattning .............................................................................................................. 7
Inledning ........................................................................................................................... 7
Utvärderingar för ansvarighet ....................................................................................... 8
Utvärderingsmetoder .................................................................................................... 12
Simulering och strukturmodeller .................................................................... 12
Eventstudier ....................................................................................................... 13
Skillnad-i-skillnader .......................................................................................... 14
Att välja mellan metoder ............................................................................................... 16
Exempel på fallstudier av utvärderingsmetoder ....................................................... 16
Några viktiga inte tillräckligt utvecklade problem ................................................... 20
Slutsatser ......................................................................................................................... 23
Executive summary ....................................................................................................... 25
Introduction .................................................................................................................... 25
Evaluations for accountability ...................................................................................... 26
The techniques of evaluation ........................................................................................ 30
Simulation and structural models ................................................................... 30
Event studies ...................................................................................................... 31
Difference-in-differences .................................................................................. 32
Choosing between methodologies ............................................................................... 33
Example case studies of evaluation methodologies .................................................. 34
Some important under-developed issues ................................................................... 37
Conclusions ..................................................................................................................... 40
1
Introduction ....................................................................................................... 43
1.1
The purposes of evaluation .............................................................................. 43
1.1.1
Accountability .................................................................................. 43
1.1.2
Assessment of specific policies ...................................................... 43
1.1.3
Assessment in the broader academic literature .......................... 44
1.1.4
Estimating damages and fines ....................................................... 44
1.2
The methodologies of evaluation .................................................................... 44
1.2.1
Simulation of structural models .................................................... 44
1.2.2
Event studies .................................................................................... 45
1.2.3
Difference-in-differences ................................................................ 45
1.2.4
Aggregate international econometric studies ............................. 46
1.2.5
Follow-up surveys ........................................................................... 46
1.2.6
Expert commentaries on specific cases......................................... 46
1.2.7
Court decisions ................................................................................ 47
1.2.8
Surveys of peer/practitioner opinions .......................................... 47
1.3
Level of sophistication or technical complexity ............................................ 47
1.4
Ex-ante versus ex-post ...................................................................................... 48
1.5
Policy areas ......................................................................................................... 48
1.5.1
Article 102 (Abuse of dominance) ................................................. 50
1.5.2
Advocacy .......................................................................................... 51
1.5.3
Education: compliance by firms .................................................... 52
1.5.4
Education: consumers ..................................................................... 52
1.5.5
Related policy areas – deregulation and liberalisation .............. 53
1.6
The central role of the counterfactual ............................................................. 53
1.7
Structure of the report....................................................................................... 53
2
The OFT’s Annual Positive Impacts ............................................................. 55
2.1.1
Mergers ............................................................................................. 56
2.1.2
Article 101: Cartels .......................................................................... 57
2.1.3
Article 102: Abuse of dominance .................................................. 57
2.1.4
Market studies ................................................................................. 58
2.1.5
Consumer protection ...................................................................... 58
3
Comparative Survey of UK, EC and USA .................................................... 59
3.1.1
Comparison of assumptions .......................................................... 60
4
Conceptual Issues in Accountability Evaluations ..................................... 66
4.1
Unobserved impact of competition policy..................................................... 67
5
Ex-post Evaluation by the Competition Authorities ................................. 70
6
Evaluation Techniques: previous literature, pros and cons ..................... 73
6.1
Simulation and structural models ................................................................... 73
6.1.1
Previous literature ........................................................................... 74
6.1.2
Pros and cons ................................................................................... 74
6.1.3
Back of the envelope (simple) simulation .................................... 75
6.2
Event studies ...................................................................................................... 76
6.2.1
Previous literature ........................................................................... 76
6.2.2
Pros and cons ................................................................................... 77
6.3
Difference-in-Differences ................................................................................. 80
6.3.1
Previous literature ........................................................................... 80
6.3.2
Pros and cons ................................................................................... 81
6.3.3
Before and after................................................................................ 82
6.4
Choosing between methodologies .................................................................. 82
6.4.1
Comparing counterfactuals: cartels as a case study ................... 84
7
Example Case Studies of Evaluation Methodologies ................................ 87
7.1
Case 1: Two UK Mergers (difference-in-differences) ................................... 87
7.2
Case 2: Cheese in Mauritius (back-of-envelope difference-indifferences) ......................................................................................................... 89
7.3
Case 3: Pirelli/BICC merger (event study) ..................................................... 89
7.4
Case 4: Antitrust fines in South African bread and flour cartels
(event study) ...................................................................................................... 91
7.5
Case 5: Volvo-Scandia (simulation) ................................................................ 91
7.6
Case 6: UK merger review (back-of-envelope simulation) .......................... 92
8
Some Important Under-developed Issues ................................................... 95
8.1
Selection bias and deterrence........................................................................... 95
8.1.1
Some potential sources of selection bias ...................................... 95
8.1.2
How much of the iceberg lies below the waterline?................... 96
8.1.3
Heterogeneity between case classes (selection bias) .................. 99
8.1.4
Existing academic literature on detection and deterrence....... 101
8.2
The need for longer term studies .................................................................. 102
8.3
The broader impact of competition policy................................................... 104
8.3.1
The effects of competition ............................................................ 104
8.3.2
The effects of competition enforcement ..................................... 106
9
Conclusions ..................................................................................................... 108
9.1
Why should CAs evaluate their own work? ............................................... 108
9.2
How should CAs conduct evaluation?......................................................... 109
9.2
What are the challenges? ................................................................................ 110
10
References ........................................................................................................ 112
7
Sammanfattning
Inledning
Denna rapport ger en översikt över de tillvägagångssätt och särskilda metoder som
används för att bedöma de ekonomiska effekterna av en konkurrensmyndighets
arbete, med särskild betoning på metodernas fördelar och nackdelar.
Syften med utvärdering
Utvärdering genomförs av konkurrensmyndigheter (CA) och/eller oberoende
akademiker/konsulter. Utvärdering kan anta många olika former, som kan delas in
i fyra kategorier

Ansvar: det finns en skyldighet att kvantifiera konkurrenspolitikens totala
fördelar, som kan uppskattas i förhållande till något på förhand angivet
mål.

Uppskattning av ett specifikt politikområde eller ett särskilt ingripande i
syfte att kontrollera kvaliteten på konkurrensmyndighetens beslutsfattande;
detta kan användas för att bidra till att göra framtida interna prioriteringar
och resursfördelning.

Uppskattning i den akademiska litteraturen har ofta bidragit vid teknisk
utveckling av utvärderingsmetoder som används av
konkurrensmyndigheter.

Att värdera skadestånd och böter kräver ofta en utvärdering av den skada
som orsakats av de berörda företagen, och därför vinsterna med
ingripanden från konkurrensmyndigheter.
Utvärderingsmetoder
Denna rapport fokuserar på tre kvantitativa huvudmetoder:



Simulering, baserad på ekonometrisk modellering i oligopolteori
Eventstudier, med bevismaterial från kapitalmarknaden
Skillnad-i-skillnader, baserat på statistisk analys av före och efter
Vi diskuterar också andra metoder mer kortfattat, inklusive: aggregerade
internationella ekonometriska jämförelser; uppföljningsundersökningar av
parterna/konkurrenterna/kunderna/leverantörerna; expertkommentarer och
domstolsbeslut; och undersökningar av kollegers/praktikers åsikter.
8
Ex-ante versus ex-post
Ex post-utvärdering genomförs retrospektivt med användning av information om
’vad som faktiskt hände sedan’, det vill säga efter att ingripandet ägde rum. För att
utvärdera effekten, jämförs sedan ’vad händer sedan’ med vad som skulle ha hänt,
om ingripandet inte hade ägt rum. Ex-ante-utvärdering kan genomföras antingen
före eller efter händelsen, men använder endast information som skulle ha varit
tillgänglig vid tiden för policybeslutet. I det fallet projicerar utvärderaren framåt
och jämför vad som skulle hända med och utan ingripandet.
Politikområden
I princip kan utvärdering tillämpas på alla konkurrenspolitikens områden, men i
praktiken har fusioner och karteller tilldragit sig mest uppmärksamhet. Enligt
författarens åsikt krävs mer forskning om utvärdering av andra områden, i
synnerhet artikel 102 (missbruk av dominerande ställning) och advokatverksamhet.
Det kontrafaktiska fallet
En huvudfråga i alla utvärderingar är att identifiera ett lämpligt kontrafaktiskt fall vad skulle hända om ett ingripande inte skett. Detta tilldrar sig ibland otillräcklig
uppmärksamhet i tidigare studier.
Utvärderingar för ansvarighet
Första delen av rapporten (kapitel 2-5) ägnas åt utvärderingar av en
konkurrensmyndighets aktiviteters allmänna effekter på konsumenternas välfärd.
Den fokuserar på de rapporterade metoderna hos de myndigheter där sådant
arbete verkar mest avancerat, åtminstone enligt vad som kan bedömas av allmänt
tillgängliga publikationer.
Storbritanniens Office of Fair Trading (OFT)
Varje år publicerar OFT en rapport över positiva effekter, som kvantifierar värdet
av de välfärdsvinster som OFT:s ingripanden ger, jämfört med kostnaderna för
dem för den brittiske skattebetalaren. De utmärkande dragen i OFT:s metod är att:




Uppskattningar uttrycks i termer av fördelar för konsumenter
Uppskattningar som regel är ex-ante, men med några ex post-fall
Uppskattningar är avsiktligt ‘försiktiga’, och presenteras som ‘punkt’uppskattningar, tillsammans med en rad rimliga världen
De flesta, men inte alla, politikområden är inkluderade i utvärderingen
För åren 2008-2011 bedömer OFT att andelen fördelar för konsumenterna på grund
av dess aktiviteter i förhållande till kostnaderna är 10:1, nästan det dubbla jämfört
med målet på 5:1. De flesta av dessa fördelar härrör från korrigering/förbud av
9
annars konkurrenshämmande fusioner, uppbrytning av karteller och effekten av
marknadsanalyser.
Vid bedömning av effekten av sina beslut om fusioner, stödjer sig OFT starkt på
simulering. Man kalibrerar modellerna med värdena låg, medelhög och hög
branschelasticitet (som ofta är en nyckelinput i modellen), och man använder
mediet som den valda punktuppskattningen. Besparingar antas räcka i två år. Offmodel-justeringar kan också behövas för att infoga något särdrag i fusionen eller
marknaden som inte fångats upp av modellen. För ingripanden mot karteller,
baseras där så är möjligt uppskattningarna på information från case-team. Där det
inte är möjligt gäller "tumregler som överensstämmer med internationell bästa
praxis och aktuell akademisk forskning": (i) i brist på ett ingripande skulle kartellen
ha existerat i ytterligare sex år; (ii) endast priset för de överträdande parterna ökas
av kartellen; (iii) kartellen skulle ha fortsatt att ta ut överpriser med 15 procent.
Vanligen utvärderas väldigt få artikel 102-fall. Metoden liknar den för artikel 101,
men med två skillnader: (i) standardprisökningen är 10 procent, (ii) varaktigheten
överlåts åt handläggarens gottfinnande i det enskilda fallet. Marknadsanalyser är
det enda område där effektutvärderingar ibland baseras på ingående ex postanalys.
OFT gör också försök att partiellt utvärdera sitt konsumentskyddsarbete. Metoden
använder data om antalet klagomål före och efter ett ingripande, och minskningar
av antalet klagomål omvandlas till ett ekonomiskt värde genom att varje klagomål
värderas till en andel av inköpsvärdet av den aktuella produkten eller tjänsten.
Jämförelse av Storbritannien, EC och USA
Om man sätter de rapporterade uppskattade fördelarna för dessa tre jurisdiktioner
bredvid varandra står det omedelbart klart att de inte är direkt jämförbara. Det
beror på att de olika myndigheterna använder olika antaganden och konventioner i
sina uppskattningar.
Det är också påfallande att uppskattningarna varierar avsevärt över tid. En orsak är
att storleken på marknaderna där ingripanden görs kan variera dramatiskt, till
exempel när stora ingripanden görs på en marknad ett särskilt år kan det leda till
ojämnheter i tidsserien. Antalet avslutade fall kan också variera avsevärt över tid.
Detta kan bero på de långvariga förfaranden som är förenade med vissa typer av
utredningar (särskilt karteller). För att minska omfattningen av svängningar i
siffrorna över tid rapporterar brittiska myndigheter tre års rörliga medeltal. En
tredje orsak till variationerna är ändringar i de antaganden som används av
konkurrensmyndigheterna.
Jämförelse av antaganden
För att uppskatta effekten av ett enskilt ingripande krävs information om
marknadens storlek, den avlägsnade eller undvikta prisökningen och hur lång tid
10
det höjda priset skulle ha gällt om ingripandet inte gjorts. Av dessa är den mest
utmanande delen av utvärderingen att uppskatta storleken på prisökningen och
hur lång tid ingripandet har effekt.
För karteller är den första bästa uppskattningen av en kartells överpriser att
använda en uppskattning som har fåtts fram under utredningen. Till skillnad från
OFT antar andra myndigheter att deras ingripande bara leder till tio procents
minskning av priset. OFT:s antagande om 15 procent verkar överensstämma bättre
med empiriska bevis i den akademiska litteraturen. Vad gäller en kartells
förväntade livslängd, om den inte hade upptäckts, använder
konkurrensmyndigheterna antaganden med vidare spridning. OFT försöker stödja
sig på bevis från existerande empiriska studier för att avgöra vad som vore det
lämpligaste antagandet, men dessa studier bygger givetvis bara på upptäckta
karteller, som mycket väl kan skilja sig från oupptäckta (det antagande som krävs
här är hur länge kartellen skulle ha fortsatt om den förblivit oupptäckt). Om man
vänder sig till ekonomisk teori för insikter är min slutsats att kartellerna är så
heterogena att ett fallspecifikt tillvägagångssätt, som nyligen antogs av EC, verkar
överensstämma bäst med ekonomisk teori.
För ingripanden mot fusioner är det ganska vanligt att använda simulering för att
uppskatta hur priset skulle ha kunnat ändras om fusionen hade fortsatt utan
konkurrensmyndighetens ingripande i specifika fall. Alternativt när effekten av en
fusion på priset uppskattats under utredningen används det ibland. Till exempel
antog EC tidigare att besparingar för konsumenter som blev resultatet av ett beslut
om korrigering av en fusion skulle bli så mycket som tio procent av
marknadsomsättningen, under det att andra myndigheter ibland har använt ett
mycket lägre standardvärde på en procent. Om man vänder sig till den akademiska
litteraturen råder ingen uppenbar samsyn om hur mycket konkurrenshämmande
fusioner vanligen höjer priset. Av den orsaken verkar simulering fall-för-fall vara
det lämpligaste tillvägagångssättet. Konvergensen är större mellan olika
konkurrensmyndigheter när det gäller hur länge den prishöjning som fusionen
leder till antas ska vara: för den lägre gränsen vanligen ett till två år; men för den
högre gränsen verkar den fall-för-fall-metod som används av EC lämplig.
För de andra politikområdena är missbruk av dominerande ställning den största
utmaningen för bedömningen. Om fallspecifik information inte finns görs flera
olika antaganden om standardprisökningen och överträdelsens varaktighet.
Emellertid gör bristen på empiriskt akademiskt arbete om missbruk av
dominerande ställning det svårt att värdera dessa antaganden. En del
konkurrensmyndigheter värderar ibland också konsumentskydd eller
advokatverksamhet. Exempelvis har FTC rapporterat antalet klagomål av
konsumenter och andelen av FTC:s ingripanden för konsumentskydd som riktar
sig mot ämnet konsumenters klagomål till FTC. Andra metoder, till exempel
undersökningar av konsumenttillfredsställelse, används också i andra länder.
11
Begreppsfrågor i utvärderingar av ansvarighet
Denna genomgång väcker några allmänna frågor för vidare diskussion och
undersökning:

Uppskattningar är uppenbarligen mycket känsliga för de antaganden som
används. En fall-för-fall-metod är därför önskvärd när det är möjligt, men
när det inte är det, finns det skäl att eftersträva gemensam praxis när det
gäller standardantaganden, och dessa bör baseras på teori och bevis.

Det är rimligt att tolka resultaten av dessa utvärderingar som typiskt
försiktiga uppskattningar. Under det att detta är lämpligt särskilt för
självutvärdering finns det en risk för att konkurrensmyndigheter kan
’underskatta sig själva’ när de rapporterar till regeringen och yttervärlden
om de fördelar som de ger.

Effektutvärderingar beaktar endast de fall då konkurrensmyndigheten hade
beslutat att ingripa, och utesluter fall då det inte skedde något ingripande.
Till exempel i fusioner finns ingen effekt förenad med fusioner som
konkurrensmyndigheten rätteligen gav tillstånd till utan ingripande, kanske
av effektivitetsförbättrande skäl.

När effektutvärderingar anskaffas av ansvarsskäl finns det en risk att
konkurrensmyndigheten kommer att välja de ’enkla alternativen’ i sina
ingripanden i stället för att driva svåra fall där det vore mer önskvärt att
använda mer resurser och skapa prejudikat, även om dessa inte ger
’mätbara fördelar’. En relaterad risk är att själva utvärderingsprogrammet
kan introducera ett ytterligare motiv för förvrängande gottfinnande i
konkurrensmyndighetens beteende. Av dessa orsaker kan det vara bättre att
ibland använda en extern revisor för att genomföra bedömningen
Det finns utan tvekan avsevärda icke observerade effekter av konkurrenspolitik särskilt avskräckande av konkurrenshämmande beteende (se nedan).
Ex post-utvärdering av konkurrensmyndigheter
Ovanstående utvärderingar är huvudsakligen ex-ante, men
konkurrensmyndigheter genomför också ex post-utvärderingar, vanligen mer på
ad hoc-basis.
Dessa utvärderingar är av två huvudtyper. Kvalitativa studier undersöker
vanligen marknaden efter ett ingripande för att fastställa om förutsägelserna vid
tiden för ingripandet har slagit in eller inte - till exempel marknadsinträde och
expansion. Kvantitativa studier försöker oftare fastställa orsakssamband mellan
ingripande och till exempel en förändring av marknadspriset. När utvärderingen
12
beställs av konkurrensmyndigheten kan en blandning av dessa två typer av metod
användas.
Det mest anmärkningsvärda publicerade exemplet är en rad beställda granskningar
för de olika brittiska konkurrensmyndigheterna och relevanta departementen.
Olika metoder har använts: bara djupintervjuer; intervjuer med marknadsaktörer i
kombination med simuleringar; DiD och en undersökning av marknadsaktörer.
Uppföljnings-frågeformulär och/eller intervjuer ger utan tvivel ofta ovärderliga
insikter men är oundvikligen behäftade med ett antal potentiella begränsningar: låg
svarsfrekvens, fördomar hos svarande, parterna har ofta korta gemensamma
minnen, och enligt deras synsätt kan ingripanden ofta tas över av andra
efterföljande och viktigare händelser.
Andra ex post-granskningar fokuserar ibland på intressenters uppfattning om
konkurrensmyndighetens arbete i allmänhet (t.ex. Storbritanniens Competition
Commission (CC) och EU-kommissionen (EC)). EC beställer också en del av sitt
utvärderingsarbete av externa experter (se nedan anförda fallstudier).
Utvärderingsmetoder
Andra delen av rapporten (kapitel 6 och 7) fokuserar mer specifikt på de alternativa
metoder som används för att utvärdera effekt i särskilda fall.
Simulering och strukturmodeller
Stimulering omfattar vanligen tre stadier: (i) en explicit formell modellering av
typen av konkurrens på marknaden, som ofta innefattar en strukturmodell som
härrör från oligopolteori, parat med en särskild modell för efterfrågesystemet; (ii)
kalibrering av modellen med numeriska värden för modellens parametrar,
härledda från direkta observationer eller från ekonometrisk uppskattning av
efterfrågesystemet (t.ex. befintliga marknadsandelar, priser och externa
uppskattningar av efterfrågeelasticiteter); (iii) användande av modellen för att
bedöma hur jämvikten skulle förändras med och utan ett ingripande av en
konkurrensmyndighet. Simulering kan vara antingen ex-ante eller ex post, men de
flesta tillämpningar är ex-ante i den meningen att de baseras på data som är
tillgängliga vid tiden för ingripandet - även om de faktiskt genomförs retrospektivt.
-
Tidigare litteratur
Den tidiga utvecklingen av simulering var fast rotad i den akademiska litteraturen
och de flesta av de fruktbärande bidragen avsåg simulering av fusioner. I ökande
grad har de senaste 20 åren simulering förekommit i specifika fusionsutredningar
av konkurrensmyndigheterna och rådgivare till parterna.
13
-
Fördelar och nackdelar
Simuleringens största styrka är dess uttryckliga användning av teori för att
identifiera det kontrafaktiska fallet. Detta underlättar ’förening’ av den analys som
genomfördes vid tiden för ingripandet med efterföljande utvärdering av politikens
effekter, och ger i sin tur en tydlig möjlighet att utvärdera de antaganden som
gjordes vid tiden för ingripandet.
Emellertid är simulering väldigt känsligt för modelleringsantaganden. Ibland är det
en styrka, t.ex. genom att det avslöjar hur känsliga förutsägelser är för det
kontrafaktiska fallets exakta art, men ibland är denna känslighet inte till någon
hjälp, eftersom det inte finns några starka teoretiska skäl att välja, t.ex.
efterfrågekurvans funktionella form. Simulering passar bättre för vissa typer av
oligopolmodeller (och därför marknader) än andra. Det är lättast att använda när
konkurrens åstadkoms genom pris och kvantitet med uteslutande av innovation,
ompositionering etc., och möjliga förändringar i beteende (relevant för
koordinerade effekter). Köpkraft har också visat sig svårt att införliva
tillfredsställande, och simulering av budgivningsmarknader är fortfarande i sin
barndom. Således är utvärdering baserad på simulering kraftigt vinklad mot vissa
typer av marknader, vilket kan leda till ensidighet vid urval av sampel. En annan
potentiell källa till ensidigt urval härrör från simuleringens stora beroende av data.
Många av de fruktbärande studierna bygger på disaggregerade datauppsättningar
av hög kvalitet konstruerade från scannerkällor; men dessa hämtas givetvis oftast
från en relativt liten uppsättning konsumtionsvaror (som ofta säljs i
livsmedelsbutiker). Slutligen är bevisen blandade för hur väl simulering förutsäger
faktiska utfall.
-
Back-of-the-envelope (enkel) simulering
Eftersom fullständig simulering är mycket data- och analystidskrävande använder
konkurrensmyndigheter ofta förenklade versioner - som vanligtvis kan
approximeras av Cournot-modellen eller enkla differentieringsmodeller
Eventstudier
En eventstudie utnyttjar data om finansmarknader för att mäta effekten av en
händelse på ett företags marknadsvärde. Om finansmarknader är effektiva kommer
effekten av någon händelse på ett företags diskonterade resultat omedelbart att
kunna iakttas genom förändringarna i dess aktiekurs. Metoden innebär mätning av
eventuella onormala intäkter förenade med en händelse (t.ex. tillkännagivande av
en fusion, och dessa identifieras som skillnaden mellan den observerade rörelsen i
aktievärderingen och den som skulle ha inträffat om händelsen inte inträffat.
14
-
Tidigare litteratur
För fusioner granskar eventstudier vanligen effekten av fusionens
tillkännagivanden och konkurrensmyndighetens beslut på värderingen av de
sammangående företagen och deras konkurrenter. Med stöd i stabila resultat från
den övervägande delen av oligopolteorin, kommer en konkurrensfrämjande fusion
att skada parternas konkurrenter, under det att en konkurrenshämmande fusion
kommer att gynna konkurrenterna. Detta framhäver metoderna i ett antal studier
av effekterna av fusionsregleringar i de viktigaste jurisdiktionerna de senaste 20
åren. Eventstudier av karteller granskar vanligen effekten av gryningsräder och
konkurrensmyndighetens efterföljande beslut på aktieägarnas lagervärderingar.
Metoden har mindre ofta använts på fall av missbruk av monopol.
-
Fördelar och nackdelar
Det centrala antagandet i en eventstudie är att finansmarknaderna är effektiva. Om
de är det ger denna metod opartiska uppskattningar som är både "objektiva" och
snabba.
Emellertid ifrågasätts detta antagande - på allmän nivå - av ett antal
kommentatorer. Mer specifikt måste, när det tillämpas på fusioner, ett antal frågor
ställas: till exempel kan en ökning av parternas aktiekurs spegla antingen
konkurrensfrämjande effekter (effektivitetsvinster) eller konkurrenshämmande
effekter (uteslutning, dominerande ställning eller hemliga överenskommelser);
avslöjar på liknande sätt ett ras i värderingarna av konkurrenterna
konkurrensfrämjande (effektivitet) förväntningar eller förutser det
konkurrenshämmande (uteslutnings-)effekter? Det finns också en möjlighet att
fusionen kan tolkas som en signal om att andra företag på samma marknad
kommer att inleda fusionsaktiviteter inom en snar framtid, som skulle öka
marknadens värdering av konkurrenter, och leda till samma tecken på förändring
som med resultat av hemliga överenskommelser och/eller dominerande ställning.
För- och nackdelarna är liknande för bedömning av ingripanden mot karteller, fast
de teoretiska förväntningarna är mindre tvetydiga. Effekten av nyheter om
utredningen och det slutgiltiga beslutet minskar nästan alltid värderingen av
parterna. På praktisk nivå kommer det trots det allmänna antagandet att
eventstudier är lätta att använda och data lätta att komma åt från ekonomiska
databaser finnas många omständigheter när lämpliga data inte är tillgängliga - i
synnerhet för onoterade bolag och/eller för konglomerat och multinationella
företag, för vilka den aktuella marknaden kanske endast utgör en liten del av dess
totala verksamhet.
Skillnad-i-skillnader
I metoden skillnad-i-skillnader, (DiD), är grundidén att utvärdera ’resultatet’ före
och efter en händelse (eller ibland före, under och efter) på den aktuella marknaden
jämfört med resultatet på en annan liknande (kontroll-)marknad, som är opåverkad
15
av händelsen. Den är vanligen ekonometrisk, och priset spåras över tid för att
inkludera för- och efterperioderna i behandlingen (t.ex. fusion) och jämfört med
detsamma på kontrollmarknaden. Nästan per definition genomförs DiD-analys
bara ex post. Fördröjningen innan den genomförs speglar en kompromiss mellan
att välja en tillräckligt lång period efter händelsen för att få en bättre uppfattning
om de långsiktiga effekterna och undvika att välja en tidsperiod som är så lång att
den skulle äventyra chanserna att hitta en användbar kontroll för att efterlikna det
kontrafaktiska fallet.
-
Tidigare litteratur
Metoden har tillämpats ganska omfattande på fusioner, ingripanden i fusioner och
karteller; det finns få exempel där DiD har tillämpats på fall med missbruk av
dominerande ställning, avskräckning eller andra effekter av offentligt ingripande.
-
För- och nackdelar
Metoden skillnad-i-skillnader är tilltalande eftersom den använder observerade
data om vad som faktiskt händer jämfört med en kontrollgrupp, där händelsen inte
inträffar. Således är det kontrafaktiska fallet inte beroende av icke testbara, kanske
restriktiva, teoretiska antaganden. Emellertid är det då avgörande att den valda
kontrollgruppen nära motsvarar vad som skulle ha hänt på den behandlade
marknaden, om inte ingripandet skett. I praktiken finns det en risk att valet av
kontrafaktiskt fall begränsas av ’vad som finns där ute’, dvs. det bästa av en
uppsättning alternativ, av vilka inget är helt lämpligt. För att bara nämna ett
exempel är den valda kontrollgruppen ofta konkurrenterna till parterna i ett
fusionsfall, men så som visas av den övervägande delen oligopolteori ändrar också
konkurrenter priserna efter en fusion, och därför är kontrollgruppen inte oberoende
av de behandlade (dvs. sammangående) företagen.
-
Före och efter-approximering till skillnad-i-skillnader
En av de oftast använda utvärderingsmetoderna är att genomföra en enkel
jämförelse före och efter av till exempel pris. Detta är i strikt mening inte någon
skillnad-i-skillnader eftersom det inte finns någon kontrollgrupp. Undermeningen
är i själva verket att det inte behövs någon kontrollgrupp, eller att det
kontrafaktiska fallet bara är status quo: om fusionen eller ingripandet inte skett
skulle marknaden helt enkelt ha presterat lika före och efter. Resultatet av en sådan
metod ska definitivt tolkas med försiktighet - man skulle åtminstone sträva efter
kvalitativa källor (t.ex. intervjuer/frågeformulär) för att underbygga valet av ett
kontrafaktiskt fall som inte förändras.
16
Att välja mellan metoder
Mycket av diskussionen om fördelarna och nackdelarna med olika metoder avser
hur träffande de implicit beskriver det kontrafaktiska fallet. Simulering placerar
genom sin karaktär valet av kontrafaktiskt fall på ett iögonenfallande sätt mitt på
scenen: en specifik oligopolmodell måste identifieras, fast detta förstås inte innebär
att rätt modell väljs. I DiD spelar kontrollgruppen rollen av kontrafaktiskt fall. Här
är valet av kontrafaktiskt fall mindre teoretiskt drivet, och metodens styrka beror
på huruvida det faktiskt finns en kontrollgrupp (med adekvata data) som är
tillräckligt lik. I praktiken kan datas lämplighet ibland dra uppmärksamheten från
hur väl detta villkor uppfylls. Under det att det är mindre vanligt att tänka på det
kontrafaktiska fallet i den typiska eventstudien, finns det fortfarande implicit där fångat av det jämförande aktieprisindex som utvärderaren använder för att beräkna
onormala intäkter. Här finns en kompromiss mellan att använda ett allmänt index,
som sannolikt är mindre känsligt för marknadsspecifika yttre händelser, och mer
skräddarsydda sektorspecifika index, som kanske inte är verkligen oberoende av
händelsen i fråga.
I en idealvärld skulle de alternativa utvärderingsmetoderna jämföras genom att
samla ett väldigt stort, slumpmässigt sampel av fall, och försöka tillämpa alla
metoder på alla fall i samplet. Under det att det är sannolikt att vissa
konkurrensmyndigheter och rådgivningskonsulter ibland genomför parallella
bedömningar under genomförandet av ett särskilt fall (samtidigt experimenterande
med till exempel en eventstudie och en simulering), förekommer de givetvis inte i
den publicerade litteraturen. Mer allmänt vore det svårt att försöka sig på en sådan
uppgift i ett stort sampel av fall, och det har i själva verket aldrig gjorts hittills.
Nästan som en utvikning från ämnet föregriper avsnitt 6.4 hur en sådan stor
jämförelse av sampel skulle kunna genomföras genom att på nytt studera en
existerande databas med uppskattningar av överpriser i karteller för ett mycket
stort sampel av olika karteller observerade i olika länder och vid olika tidpunkter.
Eftersom dessa uppskattningar härletts med en mängd olika metoder är syftet att
identifiera huruvida vissa metoder i sig med större sannolikhet genererar större
uppskattningar av omfattningen av överpriser. Under det att jämförelsen avslöjar
vissa anmärkningsvärda skillnader skulle ytterligare arbete, som mer noggrant
kontrollerar urvalet av sampel, krävas innan några definitiva slutsatser kan dras.
Exempel på fallstudier av utvärderingsmetoder
Sex representativa fallstudier används för att illustrera ovanstående metoder.
Fall 1: Två fusioner i Storbritannien (skillnad-i-skillnader)
Denna studie genomfördes av konsultfirman LEAR för Storbritanniens
Competition Commission (CC). Två olika fusionsbeslut togs i betraktande: (i)
17
GAME/ Gamestation, en fusion mellan två återförsäljare av videospel, och (ii)
Waterstone’s/Ottakars, en fusion mellan två specialiserade bokdetaljhandlare på
’huvudgatan’.
Dessa två fall illustrerar vissa av de allmänna särdragen i skillnad-i-skillnadermetoden. Kraven på data var starka. Emellertid underlättade det väsentligt att data
från tiden före fusionen redan fanns att tillgå från de ursprungliga
undersökningarna. Icke desto mindre visade det sig även i dessa två exempel rika
på data omöjligt för ett mycket kunnigt team som inte led av alltför stora tids/kostnadsbegränsningar att utföra några test av huvuddimensionen servicekvalitet. Valet av och tillgången till alternativa kontrafaktiska fall är också en
huvudfråga. I detta fall som i många andra fall med lokala detaljhandlare, är
existensen av vissa lokala marknader där bara en av parterna var närvarande före
fusionen mycket värdefull. Å andra sidan är användningen av konkurrenters priser
som en kontroll potentiellt problematisk.
Fall 2: Ost i Mauritius (back-of-envelope skillnad-i-skillnader)
Detta fall används som ett mycket nytt exempel på en intern ex posteffektutvärdering av en ung konkurrensmyndighet för dess ingripande 2010 mot
ett missbruk av monopol. Missbruket var en praxis att erbjuda retroaktiva rabatter
på processad cheddar i block av märket Kraft i utbyte mot bästa butiksutrymme i
livsmedelsaffärer. Utvärderingen genomfördes ovanligt snabbt, bara ett år efter
ingripandet av Mauritius Competition Commission (CCM). Emellertid var det två
år efter att utredningen inletts och författarna ansåg att effekten började göra sig
kännbar redan medan utredningen pågick. Erforderliga data samlades in från olika
statliga institutioner och från marknadsaktörerna själva.
Detta är ett exempel på vad vi kallar en mycket förenklad back-of-envelope
skillnad-i-skillnader, i vilken CCM förutsatte att om den inte hade ingripit skulle
det inte ha skett något inträde och priset skulle ha fortsatt att stiga i samma takt
som före ingripandet. Sådana enkla antaganden är givetvis bara gissningar och kan
ifrågasättas. Å andra sidan gör de att den erforderliga analysen blir mycket mindre
data- och tidskrävande.
Fall 3: Pirelli/BICC-fusionen (eventstudie)
Denna studie beställdes av EU-kommissionen och genomfördes av Lear
Consulting. Den avsåg Pirellis förvärv av sex produktionsanläggningar i Italien och
Storbritannien i kraftkabelindustrin från BICC General. Data som användes togs
från Datastream om konkurrenternas aktiekurser och de sammangående parternas
kunder vid tre händelser: när fusionen först föreslogs, sedan vid EC:s
tillkännagivande att man skulle inleda en fas 2-undersökning, och slutligen vid
beslutet om godkännande.
På många sätt är detta ett klassiskt exempel på en eventstudie. Just den här
branschen bör ge fruktbar mark för användning av en eventstudie eftersom många
av de relevanta företagen är stora och börsnoterade. Med detta sagt var även i en så
18
storskalig, viktig bransch som den här bara hälften av alla relevanta företag
börsnoterade, vilket väckte frågor om ensidighet i urvalet. Dessutom var många av
de börsnoterade företagen i samplet multinationella och diversifierade, vilket
väckte tvivel om värderingen av deras aktie skulle vara känslig för en fusion mellan
två av deras konkurrenter i bara två länder i bara en av deras branscher. Resultaten
tyder på att fusionen inte hade någon effekt på konkurrenterna och blandad effekt
på kunderna. Emellertid visar noggrann granskning av storleken på
uppskattningarna att de ofta är osannolikt höga, eller helt betydelselösa. Under det
att det är sant att en betydelselös effekt är förenlig med att fusionen inte har någon
negativ inverkan på konkurrensen, är den också förenlig med en mer cynisk
tolkning att fusionen (vilken effekt den än har på konkurrensen) inte skulle ha
någon märkbar effekt på den framtida lönsamheten i sådana stora multinationella
diversifierade företag.
Fall 4: Antitrustböter i sydafrikanska bröd- och mjölkarteller (eventstudie)
Detta fall använder också en eventstudie för att uppskatta effekterna av böter på
börsvärderingarna av företag som gjort sig skyldiga till överträdelser och som är
inblandade i bröd- och mjölkarteller i Sydafrika (Darj et al., 2011). Det är ett andra
exempel på utvärdering av en relativt ung konkurrensmyndighet utanför Europa.
Det är också mycket mindre tekniskt, och var förmodligen mycket mindre
tidskrävande än föregående fall. Detta fall är emellertid ett mycket bra exempel på
hur en eventstudie kan användas framgångsrikt på ett enkelt sätt för att kvantifiera
effekterna av ingripande på det berörda företaget - såsom är möjligt med böter. Det
är viktigt att effekten av böter kan överstiga kostnaderna för själva böterna på
grund av andra potentiella indirekta effekter på företagets framtida lönsamhet. Det
föreligger ingen verklig komplikation avseende det kontrafaktiska fallet, som är
ganska uppenbart i fall med böter.
Fall 5: Volvo-Scania (simulering)
Detta fall är ett exempel på en fullständig, tekniskt mycket avancerad simulering av
en föreslagen fusion mellan Volvo och Scania på den europeiska
lastbilsmarknaden. I centrum för metoden står ekonometrisk uppskattning av
efterfrågesystemet av ekvationer för lastbilar. Den använder paneldata för 16 olika
medlemsstater under två år. Priser är listpriserna för en basmodell och omsättning
är omsättningen för modellsortimentet. Den ekonometriska modell som används är
nested logit, och det är nödvändigt att inkludera variabler som speglar de olika
egenskaperna hos olika lastbilsmodeller. Emellertid, och detta är en potentiell
svaghet i uppskattningen, användes bara en verkligt teknisk egenskap - lastbilens
hästkrafter. Effekterna av fusionen simulerades sedan genom att introducera en
vald icke samarbets-oligopolmodell (dvs. ensidiga effekter) och analytiskt lösa (i)
jämviktspriserna med antagande först om ingen fusion (dvs. före) och sedan (ii)
med fusionen (dvs. efter).
19
Fallet illustrerar väl många av de vanliga styrkorna och svagheterna i simulering av
fusioner. Det tvingar analytikern att uttryckligen ange vad som är det valda
kontrafaktiska fallet, men det är också möjligt att simulera alternativa
kontrafaktiska fall (oligopolspel). I sig själv kräver strängheten i
simuleringsmodellen också att analytikern bildar sig en grundlig uppfattning om
konkurrensens och efterfrågans natur på den berörda marknaden. Å andra sidan
kan resultaten vara väldigt känsliga för alternativa antaganden, och datakraven kan
vara prohibitiva - och kräver ofta approximationer (t.ex. här bristen på mått på
produktegenskaper). Slutligen är simulering, när den genomförs på den tekniskt
komplicerade nivå som används här, uppenbarligen tids- och resurskrävande och
kräver mycket kunniga ekonometriker.
Fall 6: En genomgång av åtta brittiska fusionsbeslut (back-of-envelope simulering)
Det sista fallet använder också simulering, men denna gång mycket mer förenklat
och mindre tidskrävande. Det är en utvärdering på bred basis av åtta olika
fusioner, genomförd av konsultfirman Deloitte för ett konsortium av brittiska
myndigheter (2007). Syftet var att genomföra en genomgång av fusionsbeslut enligt
den relativt nya företagslagen 2002. Analysen baserades på två metoder. Den första
var en kvalitativ undersökning som använder intervjuer med marknadsaktörer,
kompletterad av frågeformulär och officiellt tillgängliga data. Den andra var att
genomföra ex ante-simulering på så många av fallen som möjligt, som simulerade
vad de sannolika följderna av fusionerna skulle bli, men som bara använde
information som varit tillgänglig för myndigheterna vid tiden för deras beslut.
Simuleringarna var begränsade till enkla back-of-envelope-metoder som kunde
utföras snabbt och med minimala datakrav. I själva verket var simulering, givet
databegränsningarna, bara möjligt i fyra av de åtta fallen. I vart och ett var
produkten fullständigt homogen och kapacitetsbegränsningar var typiskt nog ett
problem. Av den orsaken var den modell som användes en kapacitetsbegränsad
Cournot-modell.
Studien illustrerar mycket väl vad som kan och vad som inte kan åstadkommas
med back-of-envelope-simulering. Dess styrka ligger i snabbheten och enkelheten,
och därigenom möjligheten till tillämpning på ett antal olika fall under en ganska
kort analysperiod. Svagheten är att den ofta bara kan tillämpas på enkla marknader
(här, på vilka konkurrensen kunde beskrivas med enkla ehuru
kapacitetsbegränsade Cournot-modeller), eller på vilka enkla avvikelsetal kan
användas för att modellera produktdifferentiering. Dessutom är en risk med
simuleringsmodeller den falska känsla av precision och exakthet som de kan
ingjuta. Författarna betonade mycket riktigt att sådana simuleringar bara bör
betraktas som anordningar för att visa hur olika antaganden om marknaden och
konkurrensens natur kan översättas till olika utvärderingar av den sannolika
effekten av olika beslut. Med andra ord är deras uppgift bara att tillhandahålla ett
av ett antal olika hjälpmedel för beslutsfattande.
20
Några viktiga inte tillräckligt utvecklade problem
Enligt författarens åsikt finns det tre brister, osäkerheter och olösta problem i
tidigare litteratur och praxis som förtjänar att undersökas i framtiden.
Ensidighet i urval och avskräckning
Utvärderingsstudier tenderar oundvikligen att fokusera på ett sampel av fall som
är: (i) dokumenterade och tillgängliga i litteraturen och bland dessa (ii) vanligen de
där ett ingripande faktiskt har skett eller allvarligt övervägts, och (iii) för vilka
utvärdering är genomförbar. Detta reser allvarliga tvivel huruvida ett sådant
sampel kan ge en opartisk uppskattning av konkurrenspolitikens fulla fördelar.
Några potentiella källor till ensidighet i urval
Såsom betonats i denna rapport härrör en källa till ensidighet från det faktum att
olika utvärderingsmetoder är mindre användbara för vissa typer av marknader och
ingripanden. Men frågan är mycket större än så. Tidigare litteratur innehåller flera
andra exempel på varför utvärdering är känslig för ensidighet i urval:

I den empiriska litteraturen om karteller är det allmänt bekant att
analyserade sampel kan vara ensidiga eftersom de hämtats uteslutande från
upptäckta utredda fall, som kanske inte är representativa för den okända
populationen av oupptäckta fall.

När man bedömer hur sträng politiken avseende fusioner är, är det direkt
vilseledande att fokusera på obestridda fusioner, för även om
konkurrensmyndigheten är ’slapp’ (benägen för typ 1-fel), kommer ett
sådant sampel att inkludera många ’goda’ fusioner tillsammans med
eventuella felaktigt tillåtna ’dåliga’ (prishöjande) fusioner.

Det är allmänt erkänt att de fördelaktiga avskräckande effekterna av
konkurrensmyndigheters ingripanden sannolikt är avsevärda. Av det följer
att utvärderingar av fördelarna med en politik baserade bara på utredda fall
kan vara en allvarlig underskattning.
I rapporten presenteras ett klassifikationsschema avsett att strukturera de olika
dimensionerna av potentiell ensidighet i urval, och anvisningar för framtida
undersökningar belyses.
Hur stor del av isberget ligger under vattenytan?
I avsnitt 8.1 i rapporten ställer jag den hypotetiska frågan: "Vilken information
skulle behövas innan man kunde extrapolera från vad vi vet - baserat på
undersökta fall - till vad vi inte vet - om de fall som är avskräckta eller oupptäckta
eller inte undersökta?"
21
Om man inför tre villkorliga sannolikheter: avskräckningsgraden (ω),
upptäcktsgraden (φ), och undersökningsgraden (σ) följer det att samplet av
undersökta fall representerar bara en (kanske väldigt) liten andel, (1- ω)*(φ)*(σ), av
populationen av alla potentiellt relevanta fall.
Under det att frågan är hypotetisk är det lärorikt att som ett tankeexperiment
spekulera om den typ av storheter som är involverade. För att göra det använder vi
en ovanlig kvalitativ studie av avskräckning, beställd av OFT, som kan användas
för att kalibrera ovanstående tre parametrar. När vi för in dessa i ovanstående
uttryck antyder det att (i) det undersökta samplet fusioner bara är omkring tio
procent av hela populationen potentiella fusioner och att upptäckta karteller är
mindre än 4 procent av alla potentiella karteller; och (ii) det finns fem (15) gånger så
många avskräckta som undersökta fusioner (karteller). Emellertid måste det
betonas att dessa beräkningar är mycket ungefärliga och mycket spekulativa.
Det bör också betonas att dessa beräkningar bara avser frekvensen fusioner och
karteller - de kvantifierar inte nödvändigtvis de relativa volymerna avskräckt skada
eller missade möjligheter. Detta vore endast sant om den förväntade skadan av
observerade och icke observerade fall vore identisk. I själva verket betyder
ovanstående oro för ensidighet i urval att det finns mycket reella skäl att anta att
detta inte är fallet, dvs. att de observerade fallen inte är ett slumpmässigt sampel av
hela (delvis icke observerade) populationerna.
Rapporten granskar en del av den akademiska litteratur som mest sannolikt är till
hjälp för att främja vår förståelse av arten av och storleken på de olika potentiella
ensidigheterna i urval. Det är emellertid uppenbart att mycket framtida forskning,
både teoretisk och empirisk, kommer att behövas.
Behovet av långsiktiga studier
Det är nästan en truism att påstå att effekterna av en förändrad politik eller ett
ingripande (på vilket område som helst) sannolikt kommer att vara på lång sikt.
Det är också ganska uppenbart att utvärdering av långsiktiga effekter är svårare än
kortsiktiga utvärderingar - med tanke på risken för möjliga
sammanblandningseffekter med tiden, som gör det svårt att urskilja effekter som
orsakats av ingripandet från effekter orsakade av externa faktorer.
Detta stämmer förvisso för antitrust. Den akademiska litteraturen talar om flera sätt
på vilka en specifik händelse kan utlösa en följd eller kedja av efterföljande
händelser - vilka var och en kan utvärderas oberoende, men som i själva verket är
tydligt vägberoende. Litteraturen om endogena fusioner väcker oss till exempel till
insikt om att om fusion A godkänns, gör det en följande fusion B mer eller mindre
sannolik. På liknande sätt kan i fall med fusioner av sviktande företag följderna av
ett ingripande inkludera efterföljande förslag till alternativa fusioner av andra
parter, såsom hände i fallet med Airtours. Det finns bevis från fallstudier som talar
för att ibland när en viss konkurrenshämmande praxis förbjuds kommer företag att
22
försöka ersätta den med annan. Det har länge varit erkänt att horisontella fusioner
ibland kan vara ett alternativ som företag väljer när kartellisering är omöjligt.
Sammanfattningsvis har vad som händer efter ingripandet betydelse, och ’efter’ bör
ibland tolkas som långsiktigt och inte för inskränkt. Under det att detta ibland
erkänns i utvärderingslitteraturen är fall med långsiktig utvärdering ovanliga. Det
är författarens åsikt att framtida forskningsprogram bör prioritera långsiktigare
utvärderingar. Ett möjligt sätt att göra det är genom fallstudier av marknadens
utveckling över låt säga decennier och som involverar en rad ingripanden, snarare
än att de är begränsade till bara enstaka, oberoende utvärderingar av enstaka
händelser.
Konkurrenspolitikens vidare inverkan
Största delen av denna rapport har fokuserat ganska specifikt på effekten av
konkurrensmyndigheters ingripanden på konsumenternas välfärd. Emellertid bör
vi också ägna oss åt den vidare inverkan på ekonomin som helhet och
makroaggregat som tillväxt, investeringar, sysselsättning och produktivitet och
innovation.
Det finns empiriska studier som utforskar dessa områden, och en del av litteraturen
gås igenom i rapporten. Emellertid är det om sanningen ska fram en tunn litteratur
av varierande kvalitet. Det finns två huvudsakliga inriktningar: arbeten som
undersöker konkurrensens inverkan på produktivitet, tillväxt etc., och forskning
som mer specifikt försöker mäta effekten av konkurrensmyndigheters ingripanden på
samma faktorer. På det hela taget ger forskning av första typen en bred bekräftelse
på att konkurrens bidrar till att driva ekonomisk tillväxt, genom minst tre olika
kanaler: (i) genom att den utövar press på företagens ledning att minska
ineffektiviteten; (ii) genom att främja innovation, och (iii) genom att styra en bättre
fördelning av resurser till mer effektiva företag. Emellertid använder många studier
av denna typ tvetydiga eller tvivelaktiga mått på graden av konkurrens.
När det gäller den andra typen - effekterna av konkurrensmyndigheters
ingripanden - är en avgörande utmaning att hitta lämpliga mått på
konkurrensmyndigheters ingripanden eller konkurrenspolitik. Det har gjorts
framsteg i detta ämne och flera olika index över konkurrenspolitikens effektivitet
har föreslagits. Dessa stödjer sig vanligen på institutioners och
konkurrensmyndigheters egenskaper, till exempel graden av
konkurrensmyndighetens formella självständighet, åtskillnad mellan dömande och
beivrande funktioner inom konkurrensmyndigheten, omfattningen av
konkurrensmyndighetens utredningsbefogenheter, nivån på aktiviteterna
(sanktionernas storlek, budgetarnas och resursernas storlek etc.), och hur allvarliga
de sanktioner är som konkurrensmyndigheten kan utdöma. Det finns numera en
del bevis för att konkurrensmyndigheters ingripanden bidrar till ekonomisk
tillväxt. Emellertid behövs det mer arbete på detta område innan vi kan hävda att
detta resultat är säkert.
23
Slutsatser
Varför bör konkurrensmyndigheter utvärdera sitt eget arbete?
Jag anser att det finns minst tre starka skäl till att konkurrensmyndigheter bör
utvärdera sitt eget arbete:
För det första, om konkurrensmyndigheter ska upprätthålla och till och med öka
sina anslag från staten, är det viktigt att de kan visa att de ger valuta för pengarna.
Det är min åsikt och erfarenhet att alla väl fungerande myndigheter kan göra just
det utifrån en allsidig och offentlig utvärdering av sina aktiviteter, även med de
mest försiktiga antaganden. Denna åsikt bygger på två (enligt min åsikt) mycket
sannolika antaganden: (i) att konkurrens väsentligt ökar konsumenternas välfärd,
och (ii) de flesta konkurrensmyndigheter verkligen främjar konkurrens genom sina
olika aktiviteter.
För det andra bör regelbunden och relativt allsidig utvärdering utgöra en viktig
beståndsdel i beslut om intern resursfördelning inom myndigheten. Vid fördelning
av budgeten mellan olika aktiviteter (kontroll av fusioner, upptäckt av karteller,
övervakning av dominerande företag), är det viktigt att veta vad som är den
sannolika marginalprodukten av att spendera ytterligare en euro på varje område.
Mer allmänt bör fördelningsbeslut - säg mellan upptäckt och avskräckning präglas av en viss kunskap om utbytet.
För det tredje finns det i varje väl sysselsatt konkurrensmyndighet en inneboende
risk att när väl ett beslut har fattats eller ett ingripande gjorts det sätts in i en pärm
och aldrig mer öppnas. Ex post-utvärdering är förmodligen det bästa sättet att
säkerställa att myndigheten blir medveten om ’vad som händer härnäst’ på en
marknad. Av särskild betydelse är frågan om hur marknader reagerar på och
presterar efter ingripanden. Dessutom ger utvärdering en värdefull kontroll av
huruvida antagandena, analysen och beslutsfattandet som gjorts vid tiden för
beslutet rättfärdigas av vad som händer under efterföljande år.
Emellertid är två varningar på sin plats här. För det första bör vi inte bli slaviskt
fästa vid de exakta uppskattningar som erhålls i alla utvärderingar. Utvärdering är
alltid ett oprecist ämne, oundvikligen baserat på antaganden som är ungefärliga
och ibland inte går att verifiera. Utvärdering finns för att vägleda snarare än att
diktera. För det andra kan en övertro på uppskattningar av effekter snedvrida
fördelningsbeslut inom en myndighet. Risken är att vissa aktiviteter, särskilt
avskräckning, kan negligeras i relativt stor utsträckning eftersom effekten av dem
är svårare att mäta.
Hur bör konkurrensmyndigheter genomför utvärdering?
Två teman löper genom hela denna rapport - att erhålla uppskattningar av den
samlade effekten av en myndighets aktivitet, och sedan mer specifikt de metoder
24
som kan användas för att utvärdera enskilda fall. Det är min åsikt att
konkurrensmyndigheten bör göra båda delarna - regelbundet (kanske varje år)
utvärdera sin totala påverkan och även ägna resurser åt djupa ex postutvärderingar av åtminstone några specifika fall.
Det finns ett antal problem och beslut som skulle behöva lösas när man tar fram
utvärderingar av den totala påverkan - vilka tumregler som ska användas för
kartellers överpriser och varaktighet etc., vilka aktivitetsområden som ska
utvärderas. Här kan befintliga metoder som tillämpas av OFT, DGCOMP, FTC och
DoI användas, men i brist på internationellt överenskommen bästa praxis behöver
det inte vara nödvändigt.
Rapporten behandlar de specifika utvärderingsmetoderna och antyder att det inte
finns någon idealisk metod. Simulering, eventstudier, skillnad-i-skillnader, föreefter och mer kvalitativa undersökningar har sina styrkor och svagheter, och var
och en är mer lämpad för vissa fall än för andra. Det kanske viktigaste budskapet i
rapporten är att tillräcklig tid och uppmärksamhet bör ägnas formulering av ett
lämpligt kontrafaktiskt fall (eller alternativa kontrafaktiska fall). Ibland kommer det
kontrafaktiska fallet att diktera vilken utvärderingsmetod som bör användas.
En tredje allmän rekommendation är att myndigheten bör använda en
portföljmetod för sin utvärderingsverksamhet. Mycket talar således för att använda
en blandning av ex ante- och ex post-utvärderingar – så som de andra myndigheter
som oftast diskuteras i denna rapport gör. Likaledes bör en del av utvärderingen
använda ’back-of-envelope’-metoder, under det att en del kan vara mer grundlig
och tekniskt avancerad. Det finns fördelar med att anlita utomstående (konsulter
och akademiker) för att göra en del, men inte hela undersökningen. Det uppenbara
problemet med intern utvärdering är misstanken att den kommer att betraktas som
självrättfärdigande och bristande i objektivitet. Å andra sidan är det viktigt att
myndigheten utvecklar sin egen tekniska skicklighet.
Vilka är utmaningarna?
Förutom de tre områden där jag anser att ytterligare arbete behövs bör det betonas
att utvärderingsprojektet fortfarande till stor del är ’pågående arbete’. Utvärdering
är fortfarande underutvecklat på vissa politikområden, till exempel
advokatverksamhet, utbildning och artikel 102. Inte mycket är känt vad gäller
jämförelser om de olika metodernas förmåga att förutsäga. Här är utmaningen att
bredda utvärderingens omfattning utan att oskäligt öka kostnaderna. Som på
många politikområden spelar internationellt samarbete och spridning av
erfarenheter och kunskaper en viktig roll.
25
Executive summary
Introduction
This report provides a survey of the approaches and specific methods which are
used to assess the economic effects of a Competition Authority’s work, paying
particular attention to the advantages and disadvantages of those methods.
Purposes of evaluation
Evaluation is undertaken by either Competition Authorities (CAs) and/or
independent academics/consultants. It can take many forms, which can be grouped
into four categories.

Accountability: there is an obligation to quantify the aggregate benefits of
competition policy which can be assessed against some pre-specified target.

Assessment of specific areas of policy or a particular intervention, with the
purpose of checking on the quality of the CA’s decision-making; this may be
used to help set future internal priorities and resource allocation.

Assessment in the academic literature has often helped in the technical
development of the evaluation methodologies used by CAs.

Estimating damages and fines often requires an evaluation of the harm
caused by the firms concerned, and therefore, the gains resulting from CA
intervention
The methodologies of evaluation
This report focuses mainly on three key quantitative approaches:



Simulation, based on econometric modelling of oligopoly theory
Event studies, using evidence from the capital market
Difference-in-differences, based on statistical analysis of before and after.
We also discuss other methodologies more briefly, including: aggregate
international econometric comparisons; follow up surveys of the
parties/rivals/customers/suppliers; expert commentaries and court decisions; and
surveys of peer/practitioner opinions.
Ex-ante versus ex-post
Ex-post evaluation is conducted retrospectively using information on ‘what
actually happened next’, i.e. after the intervention took place. To evaluate impact,
26
‘what happens next’ is then compared to what would have happened, had the
intervention not taken place. Ex-ante evaluation may be conducted either before or
after the event, but only employs the information that would have been available at
the time of the policy decision. In that case, the practitioner projects forward
comparing of what would happen with and without the intervention.
Policy areas
In principle, evaluation can be applied to all areas of competition policy, but in
practice mergers and cartels have attracted most attention. In the author’s opinion,
further research is required on evaluation of other areas, notably Article 102 (abuse
of dominance) and advocacy.
The counterfactual
A key issue in any evaluation is identifying an appropriate counterfactual – what
would have happened, absent an intervention. This sometimes attracts insufficient
attention in previous studies.
Evaluations for accountability
The first part of the report (Chapters 2-5) is devoted to evaluations of the overall
impact on consumer welfare of the activities of a competition authority. It focuses
on the reported methodologies of the authorities in which such work appears to be
most advanced, at least as can be judged by publications in the public domain.
The UK’s Office of Fair Trading (OFT)
Each year the OFT publishes an annual positive impact report, which quantifies the
value of the welfare benefits of its interventions compared to its cost to the UK
taxpayer. The key defining features of its methodology are that:




Estimates are in terms of consumer benefits
Estimates are generally ex-ante, but with some ex-post cases
Estimates are deliberately ‘conservative’, and are presented as ‘point’
estimates, alongside a range of plausible values
Most, but not all, areas of policy are included in the evaluation
For the years 2008-2011, OFT estimates that the ratio of the consumer benefits from
its activities to its costs is 10:1, nearly double its target of 5:1. Most of these benefits
derive from remedying/prohibiting otherwise anti-competitive mergers, breaking
cartels and from the impact of market studies.
In estimating the impact of its merger decisions, it relies heavily on simulation. It
calibrates the models with low, medium and high values of the industry elasticity
(which is often a key input in the model), and it employs the medium as the chosen
27
point estimate. Savings are assumed to last for two years. Off-model adjustments
may also be necessary to accommodate any features of the merger or market not
picked up by the model. For cartel interventions, where possible, its estimates are
based on information from case teams. Where this is not available, it applies ‚rules
of thumb that are consistent with international best practice and recent academic
research‛: (i) absent intervention, the cartel would have existed for a further 6
years; (ii) only the price of the infringing parties is increased by the cartel; (iii) the
cartel would have continued to overcharge by 15 per cent. Typically, very few
Article 102 cases are evaluated. The methodology is similar to Article 101, but with
two differences: (i) the default price rise is 10 per cent, (ii) duration is left at the
discretion of the case officer in the particular case. Market studies is the one area
where the impact evaluations are sometimes based on detailed ex-post analysis.
OFT also attempts a partial evaluation of its consumer protection work. The
methodology employs data on the number of complaints pre- and postintervention, and reductions in complaints are converted into a financial estimate
by valuing each complaint at a proportion of the purchase value of the product or
service concerned.
Comparison of UK, EC and USA
On setting the reported estimated benefits for these three jurisdictions alongside
each other, it is immediately clear that they are not directly comparable. This is
because the different authorities use different assumptions and conventions in their
estimations.
It is also very noticeable that estimates vary considerably over time. One reason is
that the sizes of the intervened markets can vary dramatically, e.g. when a very
large market is intervened in a particular year, this can lead to lumpiness in the
time series. Also, the number of closed cases may vary significantly over time. this
may be due to the lengthy procedures associated with some types of investigations
(especially cartels). To soften the extent of oscillation of figures over time, the UK
authorities report three-year moving-averages. A third cause of the variance is due
to changes in the assumptions employed by the CAs.
Comparison of assumptions
To estimate the impact of an individual intervention, information is required on the
size of the market, the price increase removed or avoided and the length of time the
increased price would have prevailed absent the intervention. Of these, the most
challenging part of the evaluation is to estimate the magnitude of price increase and
the length of time over which the intervention impacts.
For cartels, the first best estimate of cartel overcharge is to employ an estimate
which has been thrown up during the investigation. Unlike the OFT, the other
authorities assume that their intervention leads to only a 10 per cent reduction in
28
price. The OFT’s assumption of 15 per cent seems more in keeping with the wider
empirical evidence in the academic literature. On the expected duration of a cartel,
had it not been detected, the CAs employ a wider dispersion of assumptions. It is
tempting to draw on the evidence from existing empirical studies in deciding what
would be the most appropriate assumption, but, of course, these studies are based
only on detected cartels which may well differ from undetected ones (the required
assumption here is how long would the cartel have continued had it remained
undetected). Turning to economic theory for some intuition, my conclusion is that
such is the heterogeneity of cartels, that a case-specific approach, as recently
adapted by the EC, would seem to be most in line with economic theory.
For merger intervention it is fairly common to use simulation to estimate how price
might have changed had the merger proceeded absent the CA’s intervention in
specific cases. Alternatively, when the price impact of a merger was estimated
during the investigation, this is sometimes used. Failing this, default assumptions
are made on the price impact. For example, in the past the EC assumed that the
consumer savings resulting from a corrective merger decision would be as much as
10 per cent of the market turnover, while other authorities have sometimes used a
far lower 1 per cent default. Turning to the academic literature, there is no obvious
consensus about by how much anti-competitive mergers typically raise price. For
this reason, simulation case-by-case seems to be the most appropriate approach.
There is more convergence between the CAs concerning the assumed duration of
the merger-generated price impact: for a lower bound, typically one or two years;
but for the upper bound, the case-by-case approach used by the EC seems
appropriate.
For the other areas of policy, abuse of dominance pose arguably the greatest
challenge for assessment. If case-specific information is unavailable, various
different assumptions are made about the default price rise, and the duration of the
infringement. However, the lack of empirical academic work on abuse of
dominance makes it difficult to assess these assumptions. Some of the CAs also
sometimes assess consumer protection, or advocacy. For example, the FTC has
reported the number of consumer complaints and the percentage of the FTC’s
consumer protection law enforcement actions that target the subject of consumer
complaints to the FTC. Other methods such as consumer satisfaction surveys are
also applied in other countries.
Conceptual issues in accountability evaluations
This review raises some general issues for further discussion and research:

Estimates are clearly very sensitive to the assumptions used. A case-by-case
approach is therefore desirable when possible, but when not, there are
grounds for seeking common practice on the default assumptions, and these
should be firmly based on theory and evidence.
29

It is reasonable to interpret the results of these evaluations as typically
conservative estimates. While this is appropriate, especially for selfevaluation, there is a risk that CAs may be ’selling themselves short’ when
reporting to Government and the outside world on the benefits that they
bring.

Impact evaluations only consider the cases where the CA had decided to
intervene, and exclude cases where there was no intervention. For example
in mergers, no impact is associated with mergers that the CA rightly
authorised without intervention, perhaps for efficiency-enhancing reasons.

When impact estimates are acquired for accountability reasons, there is a
danger that the CA will pursue the ‘easy options’ in its enforcement
activities, rather than pursuing difficult cases where it might be desirable to
devote more resources and establish precedents, even if these do not yield
’measurable benefits’. A related danger is that the evaluation programme
itself may introduce an additional motive for distortionary discretion in
CA conduct. For these reasons it may be better to sometimes use of an
external auditor to conduct the assessment.
There are undoubtedly considerable unobserved impacts of competition policy – in
particular deterrence of anti-competitive behaviour (see below).
Ex-post evaluation by the CAs
In the main, the above evaluations are ex-ante, but the CAs also undertake ex-post
evaluations, usually on a more ad hoc basis.
These evaluations are of two broad types. Qualitative studies typically survey the
market post intervention to identify whether the predictions at the time of the
intervention have proven to be true or not – for example market entry and
expansion. Quantitative studies more often attempt to establish causality between
the intervention and, for example, a change in the market price. When the
evaluation is commissioned by the CA then a mixture of these two types of method
may be used.
The most notable published example is a series of commissioned reviews for the
various UK CAs and relevant Government Departments. Various methodologies
have been used: in-depth interviews alone; interviews with market participants
coupled with simulations; DiD and a survey of market actors. Follow-up
questionnaires and/or interviews undoubtedly often provide invaluable insights
but are inevitably prone to a number of potential limitations: low response rates,
respondent bias, the parties often have short corporate memories, and in their view,
interventions can often be overtaken by other subsequent and more important
events.
30
Other ex-post reviews sometimes focus on the perception of stakeholders regarding
the CA’s practice in general (e.g. the UK’s Competition Commission (CC), and the
European Commission (EC)). The EC also commissions some of its evaluation work
to external experts (see the case studies cited below).
The techniques of evaluation
The second part of the report (Chapters 6 and 7) focuses more specifically on the
alternative techniques used to evaluate impact in particular cases.
Simulation and structural models
Simulation typically involves three stages: (i) An explicit formal modelling of the
nature of competition in the market, often involving a structural model derived
from oligopoly theory, coupled with a particular model of the demand system; (ii)
Calibration of the model with numerical values for the model’s parameters, derived
from direct observation, or from econometric estimation of the demand system (e.g.
existing market shares, prices and extraneous estimates of demand elasticities); (iii)
Using the model to assess how the equilibrium would change with and without a
CA intervention. Simulation may be either ex-ante or ex-post, but most applications
are ex-ante in the sense that they are based on data available at the time of the
intervention – even if they are actually conducted retrospectively.
-
Previous literature
The early development of simulation was firmly rooted in the academic literature
and most of the seminal contributions related to merger simulation. Increasingly
over the last 20 years, simulation has featured in specific merger investigation by
the CAs and advisers to the parties.
-
Pros and cons
The major strength of the simulation approach is its explicit use of theory to
identify the counterfactual. This facilitates the ‘joining-up’ of the analysis
undertaken at the time of the intervention with subsequent evaluation of the effects
of the policy, and, in turn, provides a clear opportunity for evaluating the
assumptions made at the time of the intervention.
However, simulation is very sensitive to modelling assumptions. Sometimes this is
a strength, e.g. in revealing how sensitive predictions are to the precise nature of
the counterfactual, but sometimes this sensitivity is unhelpful, because there are no
strong theoretical reasons to choose, e.g. the functional form of the demand curve.
Simulation is better suited for some types of oligopoly models (and therefore
markets) than others. It is easiest to use where competition is effected through price
and quantity to the exclusion of innovation, repositioning etc., and possible changes
31
in conduct (relevant to coordinated effects). Buyer power has also proved difficult
to incorporate satisfactorily, and simulation of bidding markets is still in its relative
infancy. Thus, evaluation based on simulation is heavily skewed towards certain
types of markets, potentially leading to a sample selection bias. Another potential
source of selection bias derives from its heavy demands on data. Many of the
seminal studies are based on high quality disaggregated datasets constructed from
scanner sources; but, of course, these are typically drawn from a relatively small set
of consumer good products (often sold through supermarkets). Finally, there is
mixed evidence on how well simulation predicts actual outcomes.
-
Back-of-the-envelope (simple) simulation
Because full-fledged simulation is extremely demanding of data and research time,
CAs often employ simplified versions – typically which can be approximated by
the Cournot model or simple models of differentiation.
Event studies
An event study draws on financial market data to measure the effect of an event on
the market valuation of a firm. If financial markets are efficient, then the effect of
any event on a firm’s discounted profits will be instantaneously observable through
the changes in its share price. The methodology entails measuring any abnormal
returns associated with an event (e.g. the announcement of a merger, and these are
identified as the difference between the observed movement in stock valuation and
that which would have occurred absent the event.
-
Previous literature
For mergers, event studies typically examine the effect of the announcements of the
merger and the CA’s decision on the valuation of the merging firms and their
rivals. Drawing on a robust result from most oligopoly theory, a pro-competitive
merger will harm the parties’ rivals, while an anti-competitive merger will benefit
the rivals. This underlines the methodologies of a number of studies of the impact
of merger regulation in the main jurisdictions over the last 20 years. Event studies
on cartels typically examine the impact of dawn raids and the subsequent CA
decisions on members’ stock valuations. The methodology has been less frequently
applied to cases of monopoly abuse.
-
Pros and cons
The central assumption of an event study is that financial markets are efficient. If
they are, this methodology yields unbiased estimates which are both ‚objective‛
and quick.
However, this assumption is questioned – at the general level - by a number of
commentators. More specifically, when applied to mergers, a number of questions
32
must be raised: for example an increase in the share price of the parties may reflect
either pro-competitive effects (efficiency gains), or anticompetitive effects
(exclusion, dominance, or collusion); similarly, does a fall in the rivals’ valuation
reveal pro-competitive (efficiency) expectations, or does it anticipate
anticompetitive (exclusion) effects? There is also the possibility that the merger may
be interpreted as a signal that other firms in the same market will engage in merger
activities in the near future, which would increase the market valuation of rivals,
resulting in the same sign of change as with collusive and/or dominant outcomes.
The pros and cons are similar for assessing cartel enforcement, although the
theoretical expectations are less ambiguous. The effect of news of the investigation
and the ultimate decision nearly unambiguously reduce the valuation of the
parties. On a practical level, in spite of the general presumption that event studies
are easy-to-use and data are easily accessed from financial databases, there will be
many circumstances when appropriate data are not available – notably, for
unquoted firms and/or for conglomerates and multinationals, for whom the market
concerned may constitute only a small part of its aggregate activities.
Difference-in-differences
In the difference-in-differences (DiD) methodology, the basic idea is to evaluate
‘performance’ before and after an event (or sometimes before, during and after) in
the market concerned relative to performance in another similar (control) market,
unaffected by the event. Typically it is econometric, and price is tracked over time
to include the pre- and post-periods in the treatment (e.g. merger) and compared
against the same in the control market. Almost by definition, DiD analysis is only
conducted ex-post. The time lag before it is undertaken reflects a trade-off between
choosing a sufficiently long post-event period to gain a better grasp of long-term
effects, and avoiding the choice of a time period which is so long that it would
compromise the chances of finding a practicable control to emulate the
counterfactual.
-
Previous literature
The methodology has been applied fairly extensively to mergers, merger
interventions and cartels; there are fewer examples where DiD has been applied to
abuse of dominance cases, deterrence, or other effects of public intervention.
-
Pros and cons
The difference-in-differences approach is appealing because it uses observed data
on what actually happens in comparison with a control, where the event does not
occur. Thus the counterfactual is not dependent on untestable, maybe restrictive,
theoretical assumptions. However, it is then crucial that the chosen control group
should closely correspond to what would have happened in the treatment market,
absent the intervention. In practice, there is a danger that the choice of
33
counterfactual is constrained by ‘what is out there’, i.e. the best of a set of
alternatives, none of which is entirely appropriate. To cite just one example, quite
often, the chosen control is the rivals to the parties in a merger case, but, as shown
by most oligopoly theory, rivals will also change price after a merger, and so the
control will not be independent of the treatment (i.e. merging) firms.
-
The before and after approximation to difference-in-differences
One of the most commonly used methods of evaluation is to conduct a simple
before and after comparison of, say, price. This is strictly not a difference-indifferences since there is no control group. In effect the implication is that there is
no need for a control, or that the default counterfactual is one of merely the status
quo: absent the merger or intervention, the market would simply have performed
identically before and after. Clearly, the results from such a methodology should be
interpreted with caution – at the least, one would look for qualitative sources (e.g.
interviews/questionnaires) to substantiate the choice of a no-change counterfactual.
Choosing between methodologies
In effect, much of the discussion about the pros and cons of different methodologies
relates to how appropriately they implicitly describe the counterfactual. Simulation,
by its nature, places the choice of counterfactual conspicuously at centre stage: a
specific oligopoly model must be identified, although, of course, this does not mean
that the correct model is selected. In DiD, the control plays the role of the
counterfactual. Here, the choice of counterfactual is less theoretically driven, and
the strength of the methodology rests on whether there really is a control (with
adequate data) which is sufficiently similar. In practice, data expediency may
sometimes distract attention from how closely this condition is met. While it is less
common to think of the counterfactual in the typical event study, implicitly it is still
there – captured by whatever comparator share price index the practitioner uses to
compute abnormal returns. Here there is a trade-off between using a general index,
which is less likely to be sensitive to market-specific exogenous events, and more
customised sector-specific indexes, which may not be truly independent of the
event at issue.
In an ideal world, the alternative evaluation methodologies would be compared by
assembling a very large, random sample of cases, and attempting to apply all the
methodologies to all cases in the sample. While it is likely that some CAs and
advising consultancies do sometimes conduct parallel assessments during their
conduct of a particular case (experimenting simultaneously with, say, an event
study and a simulation), these do not appear in the published literature of course.
More generally, attempting such a task across a large sample of cases would be
difficult, and, in the event, has not occurred to date.
34
Almost as a digression, section 6.4 anticipates how such a large sample comparison
might be conducted by revisiting an existing database of estimates of cartel
overcharge for a very large sample of different cartels observed across different
countries and at different points in time. Since these estimates were derived using a
variety of different methodologies, the purpose is to identify whether certain
methodologies are inherently more likely to generate larger estimates of the extent
of overcharge. While the comparison does reveal some noteworthy differences,
further work, controlling more carefully for sample selection, would be required
before definitive conclusions can be drawn.
Example case studies of evaluation methodologies
Six representative case studies are used to illustrate the above methodologies.
Case 1: Two UK Mergers (difference-in-differences)
This study was conducted by the LEAR consultancy for the UK’s Competition
Commission (CC). Two different merger decisions were considered: (i) GAME/
Gamestation, a merger between two specialist retailers of video games, and (ii)
Waterstone’s/Ottakars, a merger between two specialist ‘High Street’ book retailers.
The two cases illustrate some of the generic features of the difference-in-differences
methodology. The demands on data were intense. However, it helped considerably
that the pre-merger data were already available from the original investigations.
Nevertheless, even in these two data-rich examples, it proved impossible for a very
able team who were not overly time/cost constrained to undertake any tests of the
key service-quality dimension. The choice and availability of alternative
counterfactuals is also a key issue. In this case, as in many other local retail cases,
the existence of some local markets where only one of the parties was present premerger is extremely valuable. On the other hand, the use of competitors’ prices as a
control is potentially problematic.
Case 2: Cheese in Mauritius (back-of-envelope difference-in-differences)
This case is used as a very recent example of an in-house ex-post impact evaluation
by a young competition authority for its intervention in 2010 against an abuse of
monopoly. The abuse was the practice of offering retroactive rebates on Kraft
branded block processed cheddar cheese in exchange for supermarket premium
shelf space. The evaluation was conducted unusually soon, only one year, after the
Competition Commission of Mauritius (CCM) intervention. However, this was two
years after the investigation-launch and the authors judged that the impact was
beginning to be felt even whilst the investigation was underway. The required data
were collected from various governmental institutions as well as from the market
players themselves.
35
This is an example of what we call a very simplified back-of-envelope difference-indifferences, in which the CCM assumed that, had it not intervened, there would
have been no entry, and price would have continued to rise at the same rate as it
had prior to the intervention. Clearly, such simple assumptions are really only
guesses and open to question. On the other hand, they render the required analysis
much less data and time-demanding.
Case 3: Pirelli/BICC merger (event study)
This study was commissioned by the European Commission (EC) and undertaken
by LEAR Consulting. It concerned Pirelli’s acquisition of six manufacturing plants
in Italy and the UK in the power cables industry from BICC General. The data
employed were taken from Datastream on the stock prices of the rivals and
customers of the merging parties at three sub-events: when the merger was first
proposed, then at EC’s announcement that it was going to instigate a Phase 2
investigation, and finally at the clearance decision.
In many ways, this is a classic example of an event study. This particular industry
should provide fertile ground for the use of an event study since many of the
relevant firms are large and quoted on stock exchanges. Having said this, even in
such a large scale important industry as this, only half of all relevant firms were
publicly quoted, raising concerns about selection bias. Moreover, many of the
quoted sample firms were multinational and diversified, raising doubts whether
their stock valuations would be sensitive to a merger between two of their rivals in
just two countries in only one of their lines of business. The results suggest that the
merger had no impact on rivals and a mixed impact on customers. However, close
inspection of the magnitudes of estimates show that they are often either
implausibly high, or completely insignificant. While it is true that an insignificant
effect is consistent with the merger having no adverse competitive impact, it is also
consistent with a more cynical interpretation that the merger (whatever its
competitive impact) would have no noticeable effect on the future profitability of
such large multinational diversified firms.
Case 4: Antitrust fines in South African bread and flour cartels (event study)
This case also employs an event study to estimate the impact of fines on the stock
market valuations of infringing firms involved in bread and flour cartels in South
Africa (Darj et al., 2011). It is a second example of evaluation from a relatively
young competition authority outside of Europe. It is also far less technical, and was
presumably much less time-consuming than the previous case. This case, however,
is a good example of how an event study can be used successfully in a
straightforward way to quantify the effects of intervention on the firm concerned –
as is possible with fines. Importantly, the impact of a fine may exceed the simple
cost of the fine itself because of other potential indirect effects on the firm’s future
profitability. There is no real complication regarding the counterfactual which is
fairly obvious in the case of fines.
36
Case 5: Volvo-Scandia (simulation)
This case is an example of a full-fledged technically quite advanced simulation of a
proposed merger between Volvo and Scandia in the European truck market. At the
heart of their methodology, is the econometric estimation of the demand system of
equations for trucks. This uses panel data for 16 different Member States over two
years. Prices are the list prices of a base model and sales are total sales for the
model range. The econometric model used is nested logit and it is necessary to
include variables reflecting the different characteristics of different models of
trucks. However, and this is a potential weakness of the estimation, only one truly
technical characteristic was employed – the truck’s horsepower. The effects of the
merger were then simulated by introducing a chosen non-cooperative oligopoly
model (i.e. unilateral effects) and analytically solving for (i) the equilibrium prices
assuming first no merger (i.e. before) and then (ii) with the merger (i.e. after).
This case illustrates well many of the standard strengths and weaknesses of merger
simulation. It forces the analyst to specify quite explicitly what is the chosen
counterfactual, but it is also possible to simulate alternative counterfactuals
(oligopoly games). In itself, the rigour of the simulation model also requires the
analyst to form a detailed understanding of the nature of competition and demand
in the market concerned. On the other hand, results can be very sensitive to
alternative assumptions, and data demands can be prohibitive – often requiring
approximations (e.g. here the paucity of measures of product characteristics).
Finally, when conducted at the level of technical complexity employed here,
simulation is clearly time- and resource-consuming and requires highly skilled
econometricians.
Case 6: A review of 8 UK merger decisions (back-of-envelope simulation)
This final case also uses simulation but this time much more simplistic and less
time consuming. It is a broad-based evaluation of eight different mergers,
conducted by the consultants Deloitte for a consortium of UK authorities (2007).
The purpose was to conduct a review of merger decisions under the relatively new
Enterprise Act of 2002. The assessment was based on two approaches. The first was
a qualitative survey using interviews with market participants, supplemented by
questionnaires and publicly available data. The second was to conduct ex-ante
simulation on as many of the cases as possible, simulating what the likely
consequences of the mergers would be, but using only information that was
available to the authorities at the times of their decisions. The simulations were
confined to back-of-envelope simple methods which could be effected quickly and
with minimal data requirements. In fact, given data limitations, simulation was
possible for only four of the eight cases. In each, the product was effectively
homogenous and capacity constraints were typically an issue. For this reason, the
model used was a capacity-constrained Cournot model.
37
The study illustrates quite well what can, and what can not, be achieved by back-ofenvelope simulation. Its strength is in speed and simplicity, and thus the capability
of application to a number of different cases in a fairly short period of research
time. Its weakness is that it can often only be applied to simple markets (here, in
which competition could be described by simple Cournot models, albeit capacity
constrained), or in which simple diversion ratios can be used to model product
differentiation. Moreover, a danger with simulation models is the spurious sense of
precision and accuracy it might encourage. The authors correctly stressed that such
simulations should be viewed only as devices for showing how different
assumptions about the market and the nature of competition might translate into
different evaluations of the likely impact of different decisions. In other words,
their role is to provide only one of a number of different aids to the decisionmaking.
Some important under-developed issues
In the author’s opinion, there are three gaps, uncertainties and unresolved issues in
the previous literatures and practices which merit future research.
Selection bias and deterrence
Inevitably, evaluation studies tend to focus on a sample of cases which are: (i)
documented in the public domain, and amongst these, (ii) usually the ones where
an intervention has actually occurred or been seriously contemplated, and (iii) for
which evaluation is feasible. This raises various doubts about whether such a
sample can provide an unbiased estimate of the full benefits of competition policy.
Some potential sources of selection bias
As stressed throughout this report, one source of bias derives from the fact that
different evaluation methodologies are less practicable for some types of markets
and interventions. But the issue is far wider than just this. Previous literatures
include numerous other instances of why evaluation is susceptible to selection bias:

In the empirical literature on cartels, it is widely understood that the
samples analysed may be intrinsically biased because they are drawn
exclusively from detected investigated cases, which may not be
representative of the unknown population of undetected cases.

When evaluating the rigour of merger policy, it is misleading to focus on
unchallenged mergers, because even if the CA is ’lax’ (inclined to Type I
errors), such a sample will include many ‘good’ mergers alongside any
incorrectly permitted ‘bad’ (price increasing) mergers.
38

It is widely acknowledged that the beneficial deterrent effects of
competition enforcement are likely to be considerable. It follows that any
evaluation of the benefits of policy based only on investigated cases may be
a serious underestimate.
In the report, a classification scheme designed to structure the various dimensions
of potential selection bias is presented, and directions for future research
highlighted.
How much of the iceberg lies below the waterline?
In section 8.1 of the report, I pose the hypothetical question: ‛What information
would be needed before one would be able to extrapolate from what we know –
based on investigated cases - to what we do not know – about those cases which are
deterred, or undetected or un-investigated?‛
Introducing three conditional probabilities: the deterrence rate (ω), the detection
rate (φ), and the investigation rate (σ), it follows that the sample of investigated
cases represents only a (perhaps very) small proportion, (1- ω)*(φ)*(σ), of the
population of all potentially relevant cases.
While this question is hypothetical, it is instructive, as a thought experiment, to
speculate about the sort of magnitudes involved. To do this, we draw on a rare
qualitative study of deterrence, commissioned by the OFT, which can be used to
calibrate the above three parameters. Inserting these into the above expression
suggests that (i) the investigated sample of mergers is only about 10 per cent of the
full population of potential mergers and that detected cartels is less than 4 per cent
of all potential cartels; and (ii) there are five (fifteen) times as many deterred as
investigated mergers (cartels). However, it must be stressed that these calculations
are very approximate and extremely speculative.
It should also be stressed that these calculations relate only to the frequencies of
mergers and cartels – they do not necessarily quantify the relative amounts of
deterred harm or missed opportunities. This would only be true if the expected
harm of cases of observed and unobserved cases were identical. In fact, the above
concerns regarding selection bias mean that there are very real reasons for
supposing that this will not be the case, i.e. that the observed cases are not a
random sample of the full (partly unobserved) populations.
The report surveys some of the academic literature which is most likely to be
helpful in furthering our understanding of the nature and magnitudes of the
various potential selection biases. However, it is evident that much future research,
both theoretical and empirical, will be required.
39
The need for longer term studies
It is almost a truism to state that the effects of any policy change or intervention (in
whatever area) are likely to extend into the long-run. It is also fairly obvious that
the evaluation of long-term effects is more challenging than short-run evaluations given the exponential rise of possible compounding effects with time, which will
make it difficult to distinguish effects that were caused by the intervention from
effects triggered by exogenous factors.
This is certainly true for anti-trust. The wider academic literature suggests various
ways for how a specific event might trigger a sequence or chain of subsequent
events – each of which might be evaluated independently, but which are in reality
clearly path-dependent. For example, the literature on endogenous mergers alerts
us to the possibility that, if merger A is cleared, this makes a subsequent merger B
more or less likely. Similarly, in failing firm merger cases, the consequences of
intervention may include subsequent alternative merger proposals by other parties
as happened in the case of Airtours. There is case study evidence which suggests
that sometimes when some anti-competitive practice is prohibited, firms will
attempt to replace it with others. It has long been recognised that horizontal
mergers may sometimes be an alternative that firms pursue once cartelisation is
impossible.
In short, it matters what happens after the intervention, and ‘after’ should
sometimes be interpreted as long-term and not too narrowly. While this point is
occasionally acknowledged in the evaluation literature, the instances of long-run
evaluation are rare. It is the author’s opinion, that the future research programme
should prioritise longer-run evaluations. One potential way of doing this is through
case studies regarding the evolution of markets over, say, decades and involving a
series of interventions, rather than being confined to just one-off independent
evaluations of single events.
The broader impact of competition policy
Most of this report has focussed rather specifically on the impact of enforcement on
consumer welfare. However, we should also be concerned with the wider impact
on the economy as a whole and the macro aggregates of growth, investment,
employment as well as productivity and innovation.
There are empirical studies which explore these areas, and some of the literature is
reviewed in the report. However, in truth, it is a thin literature of variable quality.
There are two broad strands: works that examine the impact of competition on
productivity, growth, etc., and research that attempts to measure more specifically
the impact of competition enforcement on the same factors. Taken overall, research in
the first strand offers broad confirmation that competition helps fuel economic
growth, and this is through at least three different channels: (i) exerting pressure on
firm management to reduce inefficiencies; (ii) by fostering innovation, and (iii) by
40
guiding a better allocation of resources to more efficient firms. However, many
studies in this strand employ ambiguous or questionable measures of the degree of
competition.
Turning to the second strand - the effects of competition enforcement – a key
challenge is to find appropriate measures of competition enforcement or
competition policy. There have been recent advances on this issue with various
indexes of the efficacy of competition policy being suggested. These typically rely
on institutional and enforcement characteristics such as the degree of formal
independence of the CA, the separation of adjudicatory and prosecutor functions
within the CA, the scope of investigative powers of the CA, the level of
enforcement (size of sanctions, size of budgets and resources, etc.), and the
seriousness of sanctions that the CA can impose. There is now some evidence that
competition enforcement does contribute to economic growth. However, more
work is needed in this area before we can claim any robustness for this result.
Conclusions
Why should CAs evaluate their own work?
I believe that there are at least three strong reasons why CAs should evaluate their
own work:
First, if competition authorities are to maintain and even increase the funding they
receive from government, it is important that they are able to show that they
provide value for money. It is my view, and experience, that any well-functioning
authority will be able to do just this from a comprehensive and public evaluation of
its activities, even making the most conservative assumptions. This view is based
on two (in my opinion) very likely assumptions: (i) that competition considerably
enhances consumer welfare, and (ii) most competition authorities do indeed foster
competition through their various activities.
Second, at a more micro level, regular and fairly comprehensive evaluation, should
provide an essential ingredient in internal resource allocation decisions within the
authority. When allocating its budget between its different activities (merger
control, detection of cartels, monitoring of dominant firms), it is important to know
what is the likely marginal product of spending an additional euro in each area.
More generally, allocational decisions – say between detection and deterrence should be informed by some notion of the potential pay-offs.
Third, in any busy competition authority, there is an inherent danger that once a
decision or intervention has been made, it is consigned to a file which is then never
again opened. Ex-post evaluation provides probably the best means for ensuring
that the authority becomes aware of ‘what happens next’ in a market. Of particular
importance is the question of how markets react to, and perform, after
41
interventions. Moreover, evaluation provides a valuable check of whether the
assumptions, analysis and decision making taken at the time of the decision are
vindicated by what happens in subsequent years.
However, there are two caveats. First, we should not become slavishly attached to
the precise estimates derived in any evaluation. Evaluation will always be an
imprecise subject, based inevitably on assumptions which are approximate and
sometimes unverifiable. Evaluation is there to guide rather than dictate. Second, an
over-reliance on impact estimates can distort allocational decisions within an
authority. The danger is that certain activities, especially deterrence, may go
relatively neglected because their impact is more difficult to measure.
How should CAs conduct evaluation?
Two broad themes run though this report – deriving estimates of the aggregate
impact of an authority’s activity, and then more specifically the techniques which
can be used to evaluate individual cases. It is my view that the competition
authority should do both – regularly (perhaps annually) evaluating its overall
impact and also devoting some resources to in-depth ex-post evaluations of at least
some specific cases.
There are a number of issues and decisions which would need to be resolved in
deriving aggregate impact evaluations – which rules of thumb to use for cartel
overcharge and duration etc., which areas of activity to evaluate? Here, the existing
practices of OFT, DGCOMP, FTC and DoJ might be adopted, but, in the absence of
any internationally agreed best practice, this need not be essential.
Turning to the specific techniques of evaluation, the report suggests that there is no
such thing as an ideal technique. Simulation, event studies, difference-indifferences, before-after and more qualitative surveys all have their strengths and
weaknesses, and each is more suited to some cases than others. Perhaps the
strongest message to draw from this report is that sufficient time and attention
should be devoted to formulating an appropriate counterfactual (or alternative
counterfactuals). Sometimes, the nature of the counterfactual will dictate which
evaluation technique should be used.
A third broad recommendation is that the authority should adopt a portfolio
approach to its evaluation activities. Thus, there is much to be said for employing a
mix of ex-ante and ex-post evaluations - as do the other authorities most frequently
discussed in this report. Similarly, some of the evaluation should employ ‘back-ofenvelope’ techniques, while some might be more thorough and technically
advanced. There are advantages in commissioning outsiders (consultancies and
academics) to do some, but not all, of the research. The obvious problem with inhouse evaluation is the suspicion that it will be seen as self-justifying and without
objectivity. On the other hand, it is important that the authority should develop its
own technical capabilities.
42
What are the challenges?
Beyond the three areas where I think further work is generally required, it should
be stressed that the evaluation project is still very much ‘work in progress’.
Evaluation in some areas of policy is still under-developed, e.g. advocacy,
education and Article 102. Little is known, in a comparative sense, about the
predictive performance of the different techniques. Here, the challenge is to widen
the scope of evaluation without unduly increasing the cost. As is true for many
policy areas, there is an important role for international cooperation and diffusion
of experience and skills.
43
1
Introduction
The aim of this report is to provide a survey of the approaches and specific
methods which are used to assess the economic effects of a Competition Authority’s
work, paying particular attention to the advantages and disadvantages of those
specific methods. 1 This first introductory chapter sets the scene by providing initial
background definitions and classifications. These include the purposes and scope of
evaluation; a taxonomy of methodologies; the difference between ex-ante and expost evaluation; and the central importance of the choice of the counterfactual in
any evaluation exercise.
1.1
The purposes of evaluation
Evaluation is undertaken both by the Competition Authorities (CAs) themselves
and independent academic economists and lawyers. It can take many forms, but for
presentational convenience these can be grouped into the following four broad
categories.
1.1.1 Accountability
Increasingly, there is an obligation on CAs around the world, and to their
Governments, to quantify the aggregate benefits of competition policy (measured
perhaps by increased consumer surplus). The aggregate estimate is then sometimes
assessed against some pre-specified target to judge whether the CA has met its
required objectives. These impact evaluations typically involve using some of the
methodologies described below.
1.1.2 Assessment of specific policies
Sometimes, the purpose is to evaluate a specific area of policy, e.g. merger control
or cartel enforcement, or of the success of a particular intervention, e.g. a
prosecuted cartel, or prohibited merger. Again, this may be undertaken internally
by the CA itself or commissioned to an outside consultant or academic. Here the
objective is perhaps to check on the quality of the CA’s own decision-making – the
validity of its assumptions, rigour of its analysis and data collection etc. It may also
be used to help set future internal priorities and allocate resources.
This report draws on some of the author’s own recent work, such as a critical review of the
methods used by the UK’s Office of Fair Trading (Davies 2010), and two academic articles:
Davies and Ormosi (2010 and 2012).
1
44
1.1.3 Assessment in the broader academic literature
In the academic literature, policy evaluation appears in a multitude of guises.
Sometimes it is designed as an independent check on the performance of the CAs.
More often however, the immediate objectives of the research may be more
academic, focusing primarily on the development/testing of theory and/or
empirical techniques, with the specific anti-trust case providing a well-documented
and experimental setting. Nevertheless, many of these studies have helped in
technical developments of the evaluation methodologies used by CAs.
1.1.4 Estimating damages and fines
In any private damages case, or indeed when a CA sets a fine (where applicable),
this entails an evaluation of the harm caused by the firms concerned, and therefore,
by implication, the gains resulting from the CA intervention which removes that
harm. Expert opinions in such cases invariably draw on methodologies similar to
those described in this report.
The question of who undertakes the evaluation, and how deeply, raises important
issues of the potential distortion of incentives and priorities within the CA. We will
return to this later in the report.
1.2
The methodologies of evaluation
There is a rich variety of evaluation methodologies which have been used in the
literature to date. In this report, we shall mainly focus on what we refer to as the
three key quantitative approaches: simulation, event studies and differences-indifferences. These will be discussed at greater length in Chapters 6 and 7, but as
they are also frequently referred to in Chapters 2-5, brief preliminary definitions
will be helpful here.
1.2.1 Simulation of structural models
Simulation models typically entail modelling the nature of competition in a market,
calibrating the parameters using real world information (sometimes estimated
econometrically) and then assessing how the intervention will change the
equilibrium relative to what would have happened without the intervention. In the
academic literature, these models are often highly technical and complex, but they
are also often used for evaluation by CAs in more simplified forms.
45
1.2.2 Event studies
Event studies use the financial markets’ assessment of the impact of an event. In the
context of say merger enforcement, the events in question are the initial
announcement of the merger, the CA’s announcement of investigation, and then its
subsequent decision. The effects are quantified by comparing movements in stock
prices – both of the parties and their immediate rivals – with movements in more
general stock price indices.
1.2.3 Difference-in-differences
The difference-in-differences (DiD) methodology involves a comparison of, say,
prices before and after an event, (e.g. a merger or a dawn raid), relative to some
other real world control, i.e. a similar market without the event, or within the same
market for firms not involved in the event. Again, there are simplified equivalents
of this involving just before-after comparisons without a control market, sometimes
in multivariate form with control variables included.
We shall interpret each of these categories fairly broadly to encompass much
simpler methods which can be seen as special forms of one or the other of the
categories. Like any taxonomy of this sort, it is bound to entail a certain degree of
arbitrariness, but this is a price worth paying for the expositional convenience it
brings. There are a number of alternative taxonomies used in the recent literature,
e.g. Bergman (2008), Buccirossi et al. (2006), OXERA (2009).2 The first two are
sufficiently similar to our own for us to merely refer the interested reader to the
original papers, but OXERA (2009) is sufficiently different to merit a short
summary. The authors group the existing methods and models into three broad
types:

Comparator based, which includes (i) DiD, (ii) cross-section (across firms,
markets or countries) econometrics or averages, and (iii) time series
econometrics or interpolation for during, before and/or after.

Market structure based using industrial organisation (IO) models, especially
structural models.

Financial analysis based, including event studies but also other more
descriptive techniques from the accountancy/finance literatures.
OXERA (2009) is a commissioned study report for the European Commission on quantifying
antitrust damages. There are obvious parallels (although by no means always exact) between the
savings that CAs achieve for consumers from removing anti-competitive practices and claims for
damages against defendants responsible for inflicting losses on their customers and rivals and/or
suppliers.
2
46
This taxonomy is more exhaustive than our own, but the three categories
correspond fairly closely to our own categories.
Other methodologies
There is also a variety of other, mainly qualitative (with the exception of the first),
approaches which we shall refer less frequently to below.
1.2.4 Aggregate international econometric studies
International econometric studies are more aggregate studies, employing crosscountry or panel data in order to identify the effects of competition policy on macro
or sector aggregates, e.g. price-cost margins, GDP, productivity. These are
discussed and well summarised by Bergman (2008), who provides some of the key
references. Necessarily they confront daunting measurement issues, often relying
on the construction of subjective indexes of the ‘severity of competition policy’
which are allowed to differ across countries. Other econometric problems are
familiar in any international comparisons based on production functions or related
concepts, e.g. identification, simultaneity and the requirement that the underlying
functional forms are stable across countries. In general, this report does not cover
studies of this very aggregate type, but the final section does include a slightly
more detailed survey.
1.2.5 Follow-up surveys
It is quite common for CAs to undertake or commission reviews of their previous
cases, (especially mergers). For example the UK Competition Commission (CC),
together with the Office of Fair Trading (OFT) and the relevant Government
Department, regularly conducts (or commissions) retrospective merger reviews,
reflecting upon market developments following merger interventions. These
reviews often use follow up questionnaires and/or interviews with the interested
parties and related firms. These can provide invaluable insights and are discussed
further below in Chapter 5 on ex-post evaluation by the CAs.
1.2.6 Expert commentaries on specific cases
Book collections of expert (economic) commentaries on specific, often well known
anti-trust case studies, such as Kwoka and White (2004) and Lyons (2009) for the US
and EU respectively, can also be viewed as contributing to the evaluation literature,
but for obvious reasons, it is difficult to generalise from a set of heterogeneous non-
47
randomly selected small samples, especially with respect to the evaluation
methodologies used (if any).
1.2.7 Court decisions
Some studies have assessed the quality of CA decision-making by the frequency of
court appeals and/or the success rates in those appeals (see Bergman (2008, p.38991) for a brief survey). For certain purposes this may be a valuable extra source of
(presumably well-informed and objective) evaluation, but obvious limitations
include the likelihood of selection bias, and the fact that court decisions will
sometimes involve judgement on the correctness of legal process rather than
economic substance.
1.2.8 Surveys of peer/practitioner opinions
Certain high-profile annual reviews provide an alternative approach, based on peer
review evaluation of the performance of different CAs around the world, e.g. the
Global Competition Review and OECD country reviews. These enable international
comparisons over time at the aggregate level, but lie outside our current remit,
being based on subjective opinion rather than quantitative methodologies.
1.3
Level of sophistication or technical complexity
Depending on the purpose, the budget, and who undertakes the evaluation, the
sophistication of evaluations can vary considerably. Broadly speaking, there are
three degrees of technical complexity:

Full blown, ‘state of the art’ applications: these involve sometimes very
detailed Industrial Organisation theory and advanced econometric
methods. Many of the academic case studies fall into this category, as do
some ex-post case evaluations conducted by the CAs or commissioned
reports.

‘Back-of-envelope’: these are much simpler versions, especially of
simulation or differences-in-differences, where the practitioner employs
easy and quick to compute approximations to the above. A typical ‘back-ofenvelope’ evaluation might require only days or hours to conduct, while the
full blown equivalent might require months (or even years in some
academic cases).

Default: these are employed, especially in the accountability exercises
described in Chapters 2-4, where a large number of cases need to be
evaluated fairly quickly and cheaply and hard data are sometimes sparse.
48
1.4
Ex-ante versus ex-post
Evaluation may be either ex-ante or ex-post. Although the meaning of this
dichotomy is superficially obvious, these terms are sometimes misunderstood. By
definition, the latter is backward-looking – what outcome would have happened,
had say, a cartel not actually existed; while ex-ante looks forward – anticipating
whether or not, say, a merger would have coordinated effects, if cleared.
In practice, however, both ex-ante and ex-post evaluations are typically conducted
retrospectively, and the meaning of the distinction relates mainly to the nature of
the data used in the evaluation. Thus, an ex-post evaluation uses the information of
‘what actually happened next’, i.e. after the intervention took place. To evaluate
impact, ‘what happens next’ is then compared to what would have happened, had
the intervention not taken place.3 When the perspective is ex-ante, but conducted
after the event, this generally only employs the information that would have been
available at the time of the policy decision. In that case, the practitioner projects
forward comparing of what would happen with and without the intervention.
In general, ex-ante evaluation is simpler to conduct given that it makes less demand
on data – employing information which should be available at the time of the policy
decision. Ex-post evaluation, on the other hand, can only be conducted some years
after the intervention when accurate data becomes available on what actually did
happen. It is also confounded by the likelihood that what happens next will not be
exclusively due to just the intervention. This is discussed further at greater length
in the specific context of merger remedies by Davies and Lyons (2007 pp.106-7).
Usually, differences-in-differences, event studies and qualitative studies are only
applied in ex-post form, while simulation may be used for both ex-ante and ex-post
evaluations.
1.5
Policy areas
Most of this report will be largely confined to the evaluation of competition policy,
defined to include all activities undertaken by competition law enforcement
agencies. However, at the end of this section we briefly discuss the related areas of
de-regulation and liberalisation which are more typically the territory of other areas
of government including specific sector regulators.
This comparison is not without difficulties. For example, when retrospectively evaluating the
impact of a particular merger intervention, should actual post-merger prices be compared with
those projected from the simulation model, or should these projections be adjusted for any postintervention exogenous shocks, say a demand shock? Estimating the separate impact of such
exogenous shocks is typically not straightforward
3
49
Table 1.1 provides an assessment of the extent of the existing literature for each
component part of competition enforcement, distinguishing between the academic
literature and CAs’ evaluation reports.4 It also classifies by the extent to which the
three key methodologies have been applied in these parts.
Table ‎1.1
Extent of evaluation literature by broad area of competition policy
Methodology
Academic
Literature
CAs
Simulation
Extensive
Extensive
Event Studies
Extensive
Some
DiD etc
Extensive
Some
Simulation
Some
Few
Event Studies
Some
Few
DiD etc
Some
Some
Simulation
Few
Very few
Event Studies
Few
Very few
DiD etc
Few
Very few
Advocacy
None
None
None
Compliance
None
None
None
Consumer Education
None
None
None
Enforcement:
Merger control
Cartels/Article 101
Abuse/Article102
Non-enforcement:
Source: Author’s assessment
Thus, most of the previous literature has concentrated on mergers and cartels. The
academic literature is most developed and extensive for mergers, and includes
highly influential contributions on simulation, but also event studies and DiD. In
turn, these have had a strong impact on the evaluations undertaken by the CAs
themselves, and it is commonplace for the major CAs to apply simulation models in
their own evaluations. There is also an extensive literature on cartel overcharge,
This assessment is probably uncontroversial and is broadly consistent with the emphases in
literature surveys by other commentators, for example, Bergman (2008) and Werden (2008).
4
50
with ad-hoc versions of DiD being more frequent. CAs sometimes employ the latter
in their evaluations of the consumer benefits from cartel-busting.
Since mergers and cartels feature extensively throughout the remainder of this
report, the remaining preliminary comments here are confined to the other areas
where evaluation has been much less common.
1.5.1 Article 102 (Abuse of dominance)
Our judgement that evaluation of cases involving abuse of power (Art 102) has
been far less common than for mergers and cartels is inevitably impressionistic, but
the following fragments of evidence strongly suggest that it is valid. Davies’s
review (2010, Table 4.2) of the OFT’s Impact Estimates, reveals that for 2006-2009,
while the OFT were able to evaluate 20 mergers, only one case of Article 102
enforcement was assessed. OXERA, in its report for the EC (OXERA, 2009, p.16)
suggests that ‚There have been relatively few cases of exploitative abuse of
dominance found by competition authorities or courts, either at the EU level, or in
the Member States‛. In the US, Werden (2008, p.446) suggests that ‚Non-merger
civil enforcement accounts for relatively few cases and for far less consumer
savings than either criminal or merger enforcement‛.5 Similarly, within the
academic literature, relevant studies are relatively few. This is probably
symptomatic of a more general scarcity of empirical IO work in the broad area of
Article 102. For example, Slade (2008) concludes her survey of the empirical
literature on the effects of vertical restraints (p.28) by suggesting that ‚Perhaps the
most important lesson that can be learned < is how scant that evidence is,
especially when compared to the amount of theoretical research.‛
There are two obvious explanations for this. The first is, simply, that CAs bring
relatively few cases of Article 102 abuse to fruition, and the second is that
evaluation is unusually difficult to conduct in these cases. Werden (2008, pp. 442-3)
suggests that, certainly, the latter is true: ‚In assessing the effects of antitrust
enforcement, cases involving exclusionary conduct present the greatest challenge.
The effects of potentially exclusionary conduct are apt to be subtle and can be
experienced long after the conduct itself.‛ He points to the difficulties in
establishing the extent to which rivals are harmed and the impact on consumers,
and explains that delicate trade-offs are involved where the practice may entail an
element of efficiency enhancement. He also identifies predatory behaviour cases as
particularly problematic, given the need to quantify short-run and long-run
impacts of opposite directions.
He defines non-merger civil enforcement as ‚single-competitor exclusionary conduct, vertical
restraints and agreements among competitors other than hard-core cartels or mergers‛.
5
51
1.5.2 Advocacy
Typically, competition authorities allocate a significant proportion of their budget
to advocacy activities. An International Competition Network (ICN) (2002) study
on competition advocacy reports that, amongst those countries that felt able to
quantify the resources they devoted to advocacy, almost one third reported that
this was as high as between 20 and 30 per cent of their budget. Despite this, there
has been little research attempting to quantify the impact of competition advocacy.
The reasons why are entirely understandable, once one attempts to define the term.
The ICN defines advocacy as:
‚those activities conducted by the competition authority related to the promotion of a
competitive environment for economic activities by means of non-enforcement
mechanisms, mainly through its relationships with other governmental entities and by
increasing public awareness of the benefits of competition.‛
Inevitably, much of this activity is general and intangible in nature, with specific
effects that are not at all amenable to measurement. In the circumstances, it is
inevitable that most of the work that has been done is predominantly qualitative.
For example, the OFT (2010b) conducted a survey of UK government officials
across various government departments asking how far its competition related
advice was taken into consideration and influenced policymakers. Judged on the
responses received from 43 respondents, it seems that advocacy did indeed have a
significant impact – leading to important changes in policy approaches in half of
the cases, and changes in objectives in one quarter. However, this study did not
attempt to quantify this impact. Other authorities who have also carried out
detailed surveys to assess the impact of their advocacy activities include the Federal
Trade Commission's Bureau of Competition (FTC) and the Italian Competition
Authority.6
Evenett (2006), in a thought-provoking commentary questions the real value of
such qualitative studies – if somewhat over-critically. However, it would be wrong
to merely dismiss qualitative work since it can often establish that advocacy can
sometimes have very real pay-offs, even if they are difficult to measure.
The OFT study also describes three specific case studies which illustrate quite well
that (i) advocacy can have important positive impacts, but that (ii) they are difficult
to measure. The first case study regarded the advice given to the Ministry of Justice,
warning against licensing regulations that would have posed a very serious barrier
to entry into the market for will-writing; the second related to energy-efficiency in
light bulbs, on which the OFT warned against voluntary arrangements which might
facilitate collusion; the third was on how to improve procurement guidelines for
competitive tendering in public procurement of waste management services. In
The FTC study is referred to in Majoras (2005). For the Italian study see Arisi and Esposito
(2007).
6
52
principle, it would be possible to quantify the impact, although this particular
study did not do so, I suspect, because of cost and time constraints. None of the
cases would be simple to evaluate and each would inevitably involve speculation.
For example, in the light bulb case, speculation would be needed on the probability
that collusion would have occurred, and the extent of that collusion. An obvious
question is whether the methods used for assessing merger and cartel enforcement
could be applied also to measuring the impact of advocacy. A particular problem
would be to identify the right counterfactual. For instance, in measuring the impact
of advocacy that resulted in the dropping of a piece of draft legislation which
would have had anticompetitive consequences, we would need to know what
would have happened had the anticompetitive proposal been enacted. For
enforcement activities, such as cartels, there is always the possibility of using a
similar market as counterfactual, but in this case it would have to be a similar
jurisdiction, something that would be even harder to find.7 It would also be difficult
to identify what version of the proposed legislation would have been accepted in
absence of successful advocacy efforts.
None of this is to deny that some sort of evaluation would be possible and, in my
opinion, desirable. However, it would be wise, in these circumstances, if the
evaluation was run under a number of different scenarios.
1.5.3 Education: compliance by firms
Encouraging business compliance with competition law is a potentially important
dimension of CA activity. However, attempts to measure the efficacy of compliance
programmes per se are rare.8 In one example, OFT (2010a) presents some survey
findings designed to understand what motivates business compliance and includes
examples of their compliance activities. Responding firms mentioned reputational
damage, financial penalties, individual sanctions (e.g. risk of criminal proceedings)
as key motivations for compliance. Compliance is obviously linked to deterrence,
which we discuss more generally in later sections.
1.5.4 Education: consumers
Much consumer education relates to consumer protection law and falls outside our
remit. However, insofar as better educated consumers should be less frequently
exposed to asymmetric information, reduced market imperfections might enhance
It may be equally hard to show that a proposed piece of legislation was prevented as a result of
advocacy rather than other political considerations.
7
The scarcity of evidence also reflects the fact that in many countries the CA is not allowed to
carry out compliance activities.
8
53
competition between firms. Again, this is an under-researched area, but some CAs
are beginning to work on evaluation in this area. 9
1.5.5 Related policy areas – deregulation and liberalisation
The main focus of this report is on ‘competition policy proper’, relating to the
enforcement of competition law. However, there are other policy areas which
should also be briefly mentioned. In particular, liberalisation and privatisation (and
potentially those advocacy activities of CAs that may trigger liberalisation) should
be, and is, also evaluated – quite often with more emphasis on the long-term
impacts. These are discussed below in section 8.2.
1.6
The central role of the counterfactual
A central issue running throughout most antitrust analysis is the choice of the
counterfactual, i.e. what would have happened had some event, practice, policy
intervention not occurred? This is not just a concern for academic economists. It
also occupies the attention of the courts and lawyers, for example when attempting
to quantify damages.10
Equally, it follows that any particular quantitative methodology used to evaluate a
specific case must necessarily entail a choice of counterfactual, even if it is
sometimes only implicit. The choice of counterfactual has both conceptual and
empirical dimensions – which counterfactual is theoretically most tenable, and how
do we calibrate it with plausible estimates of key parameters?
We return to this issue in section 6.4 below when comparing different
methodologies.
1.7
Structure of the report
The remainder of this report has seven chapters arranged in three broad parts. The
first part includes Chapters 2-5 relating to ‘evaluation for accountability’. It
describes those evaluations, which are designed to be comprehensive, in that they
cover all (or most) of a CA’s interventions in a given year. Chapter 2 begins with
the UK’s Office of Fair Trading (OFT) which has been very active in this area.
Chapter 3 provides a comparison of such evaluations for the three jurisdictions
most prominent in this area: the US, EC and UK. Chapter 4 considers some of the
9
See OFT (2011c) p.30 fn.45, and OECD (2002)
For a useful cross-discipline of the use of counterfactuals in antitrust and mergers, see Colley
and Marsden (2010)
10
54
conceptual issues and problems raised by such evaluations. Chapter 5 turns to the
use of ex-post evaluation by the CAs.
The second part of the report turns more specifically to the individual quantitative
methodologies used in evaluations of all types. Chapter 6 provides a survey of the
previous literatures on each of the three main methodologies (simulation, event
studies and differences in differences) and discusses their relative advantages and
disadvantages. Chapter 7 presents six specific cases to illustrate how these
methodologies have been used for evaluation.
Finally, Chapter 8 points to some of the areas in which the author believes further
research is most required, and Chapter 9 concludes.
55
The OFT’s Annual Positive Impacts
2
This and the following three sections focus on (mainly) aggregate evaluations of a
CA’s activity - what was referred to as the ‘accountability’ purpose in section 1.1.
The term ‘aggregate’ indicates that the evaluation is comprehensive across the
broad range, or most of, the CA’s activity. Thus, this will typically involve scores of
cases in a given year, rather than just focusing on a particular case intervention.
CAs have been publishing information relevant to their impact for a long time.
However, traditionally, this was limited to descriptive statistics and reports on the
number of cases pursued, and/or the number of successful cases. Increasingly, this
reporting obligation has begun to extend to more sophisticated measures, where
the CA has quantified and reported on the aggregate benefits of competition policy
(measured perhaps by increased consumer surplus). This aggregate estimate is then
assessed against some pre-specified target to judge whether the CA has met its
required objectives.
This section begins by describing the impact evaluations undertaken by the UK’s
Office of Fair Trading on an annual basis – the most recent example being year
2010/11. 11 OFT is highlighted for two reasons: (i) the author has worked with and
advised the OFT’s impact evaluations over a number of years, and is therefore very
familiar with them at first hand; (ii) of all the authorities around the world, the OFT
has been the most transparent and prolific in publishing details of its work in this
area. Chapter 3 will then introduce the other jurisdictions who conduct and publish
evaluations most similar to the OFT: DoJ (Department of Justice) and FTC (The
Federal Trade Commission's Bureau of Competition) in the US and the European
Commission (EC). These are the authorities for whom methods of impact
evaluation are most developed, at least as well as can be judged by documents in
the public domain. Some other jurisdictions around the world have also attempted
overall assessments which estimate the consumer benefits of competition
enforcement, but these are only sporadic and less regular. Davies (2010, Appendix
B) provides a brief survey of these. Chapter 4 then enumerates some of the most
important conceptual issues raised in accountability studies of this sort. Chapter 5
describes the use ex-post evaluations by the CAs, which are usually less
comprehensive and more case-specific.
Each year the OFT publishes an annual report which quantifies the value of the
welfare benefits of its interventions compared to how much it costs the UK
taxpayer. While this evaluation would ideally assess the benefits of all the cases it
handles, for practical reasons, it is only possible for a large number, but not all,
cases. There are six defining features of the methodology:
11
The most recent at the time of writing is OFT (2011c). See also Davies’s evaluation (2010).
56

Estimates are in terms of consumer benefits, reflecting the fact that
competition enforcement should be guided by the consumer welfare
standard.

Estimates are generally ex-ante, but with some ex-post cases.

Estimates are deliberately ‘conservative’.

It is assumed that no intervention can have a negative impact.

Estimates are presented as ‘point’ estimates, rather than as a range of
plausible values.

Most areas of policy are included, but, to date, consumer education and
deterrence are two major exclusions, pending further work.
Table 2.1
Estimated average annual consumer savings and OFT costs 2008-11
Competition enforcement
(Art 101&102)
Merger control
Market studies, reviews of
orders & undertakings
Consumer protection
enforcement
Totals
Benefits
(£mn)
83 (25%)
Partial Costs (£mn)*
Benefit/Costs
34
9.59
90 (28%)
117(36%)
36 (11%)
326
* Partial costs are the costs attributable to these activities (no disaggregation across areas published). Including
costs attributable to OFT’s other activities, the total rises to £48mn. If total costs are used as the denominator, the
ratio falls to 6.8, however, this would imply, incorrectly that the other activities led to zero benefits.
Source: OFT (2011a) Table 1.1.
Table 2.1 summarises the OFT’s estimates of consumer savings for 2008-2011. As
can be seen, in aggregate the ratio of benefits to costs (9.59) is nearly double the
target of 5:1 it has agreed with the UK’s Treasury. Nearly all of these benefits derive
from remedying/prohibiting otherwise anti-competitive mergers, breaking cartels
and market studies. Very briefly, the methods and assumptions it uses in each of
these areas is as follows.
2.1.1 Mergers
The OFT relies very heavily on simulation. For any particular merger the model is
chosen, as appropriate, from three candidates – Cournot for homogeneous products
and PCAIDS (Proportionally-calibrated Almost Ideal Demand System) or ALM
57
(Antitrust Logit Model) for differentiated product industries.12 For vertical mergers,
simulation is done for each stage separately. The estimates of consumer benefit
resulting from this methodology represent 'conservative point-estimates', in the
sense that ‘any assumptions made to run the model are conservative.’ The model is
calibrated using low, medium and high assumed values of the industry elasticity
(which is often a key input in the model), and uses the medium as the chosen point
estimate. The conservatism relates to the range of the elasticity assumptions.
Savings are assumed to last for two years. Thereafter, market correction (e.g. entry)
is assumed to wipe out any anti-competitive consequences. Off model adjustments
may also be necessary to accommodate any properties of the merger or market not
picked up by the models.
Where simulation is not appropriate – either because none of the above models
adequately describes the nature or competition, or because data for calibration are
unavailable – the OFT uses a default assumption. This is that the consumer savings
as a proportion of turnover are equal to the mean of the lower bound ratios across
all the mergers which could be simulated in that year.
2.1.2 Article 101: Cartels
Where possible, estimates are based on information from case teams, but where this
is not available, OFT applies ‚rules of thumb that are consistent with international
best practice and recent academic research‛:

Future cartel duration prevented. Absent intervention, the cartel would exist
for a further 6 years,

Affected turnover. This is assumed to be only the turnover of the infringing
parties. This is conservative, to the extent that a high cartel price allows
competing outsiders to free-ride by raising their own price up towards the
cartel’s price.

Extent of the avoided price-raise. This is estimated if possible during the
investigation. Where not, 15 per cent is assumed.
2.1.3 Article 102: Abuse of dominance
There have been typically very few Article 102 cases evaluated. The methodology is
similar to Article 101 evaluations, but with two differences: (i) the default price rise
Increasingly in recent years this ‘simulation’ is based on estimates undertaken at the time of
the investigation of the likely Upward Pressure on Prices (UPP) or related techniques (OFT
2011d).
12
58
is 10 per cent, (ii) duration is left at the discretion of the case officer in the particular
case.
2.1.4 Market studies
Again, the use of conservative assumptions is stressed, but this is the one area
where the impact evaluations are not always ex-ante. It is explained that
subsequent monitoring of market developments may lead to revised assumptions
and updated impact estimates, and where possible, use is also made of ex-post
impact estimates.
2.1.5 Consumer protection
At the heart of the methodology here are data on the number of complaints against
targeted traders, pre- and post-intervention. Any reduction in complaints is
converted into a financial estimate of avoided consumer detriment by valuing each
complaint at a proportion of the purchase value of the product or service
concerned. That proportion is calculated using a standard formula which has been
previously estimated from survey data on consumer detriment relative to purchase
price. This is then grossed up to allow for additional benefits of (i) consumers who
had not complained against the trader concerned, and (ii) consumers of other firms
who were also engaging in similar practices who, it is assumed, are now persuaded
to also cease the practice.
59
3
Comparative Survey of UK, EC and USA
Apart from the OFT, the other major other jurisdictions in which impact
estimations are regularly reported are the USA (DoJ and FTC) and the European
Union, by the European Commission (EC). Table 3.1 displays the reported
estimated benefits (also shown as a percentage of GDP) for these three jurisdictions.
The figures are expressed in terms of consumer benefits or consumer savings,
which reflects the CAs’ approach to the general objectives of competition policy. It
must be stressed that the purpose of this table is not to compare the performance of
these authorities, but to illustrate the sort of magnitudes and to demonstrate some
of the difficulties in interpreting these estimates. The figures were collected from
CAs’ respective annual reports13, and to avoid excessive repetition, the detailed
references of individual items are not referenced separately in the following.
One immediately noticeable feature of these figures is the variability over time in
some instances. One reason for this is that the sizes of the intervened markets and
the scope of the cases can vary dramatically, e.g. when a very large market is
intervened in a particular year, this can lead to lumpiness in the time series. Also,
the number of cases may vary significantly over time. Fluctuations in the annual
number of closed cases may be due to the lengthy procedures associated with some
types of investigations (especially cartels). For example a relatively large number of
on-going cartel investigations in the US DoJ in 2010 would mean high agency
activity, but only low measured impact in 2010, followed by higher reported
impacts in subsequent years. The EC displays a more evenly distributed impact
(over time), which probably implies smaller variance in the relevant market sizes
and/or shorter procedures. To soften the extent of oscillation of figures over time,
the UK authorities report three-year moving-averages. Another cause of the
variance in the estimates over time is changes in the assumptions employed by the
CAs, as discussed further below. For example, the large increase in estimated
impact in cartels in the EC between 2009 and 2010 can be explained by changes in
the authority’s changed assumption about the cartel life-span assumption (see
Table 3.2).
Unless otherwise mentioned, the sources are EC (2010), USDoJ (2012), USFTC (2011) and OFT
(2011a).
13
60
Table 3.1
CA estimates of annual consumer benefits from interventions14
Cartels
Consumer saving
% of GDP
×10-4
EC (billion EUR)
2010
7.2 (7)
5.87
2009
1.2 (6)
1.02
2008
1.7 (7)
1.36
2007
3.815 (8)
3.06
USDOJ16 ($ billion)
2010
0.05 (60)
0.03
2009
0.60 (72)
0.42
2008
0.02 (54)
0.01
2007
0.56 (40)
0.41
USFTC ($ billion)
2010
N/A
–
2009
N/A
–
2008
N/A
–
2007
N/A
–
**
UK CC+OFT (£ billion)
2009/10
0.083
0.57
2008/09
0.083
0.59
2007/08
0.083
0.57
Mergers
Consumer
% of GDP
saving
×10-4
Other antitrust
Consumer
% of GDP
saving
×10-4
4.2-6.3(16)
5.6 (16)
5.5 (24)
NR (23)
4.28
4.77
4.41
–
NR (58)
2.0 (54)
4.3 (111)
NR (133)
–
1.70
3.45
–
0.19* (19)
1.02 (12)
0.48 (16)
0.15 (12)
0.13
0.72
0.33
0.11
0.19*(4)
0.02 (2)
0.05 (4)
0.02 (2)
0.13
0.01
0.03
0.01
0.59 (16)
0.79 (13)
0.36 (13)
0.81 (20)
0.40
0.55
0.25
0.58
0.51 (6)
0.19 (7)
0.03 (4)
0.08 (11)
0.35
0.13
0.02
0.06
0.235 (11)
0.229 (15)
0.309 (14)
1.62
1.64
2.13
0.083
0.083
0.083
0.57
0.59
0.57
NR denotes not reported
* Merger and other civil antitrust combined in 2010.
** Cartels and other antitrust combined for all years. Sources: see footnote 14
3.1.1 Comparison of assumptions
To estimate the impact of an individual intervention, information is required on: (i)
the size of the market concerned, (ii) the price increase removed or avoided and (iii)
the length of time the increased price would have prevailed absent the intervention.
Of these, market size is the easiest to estimate. This information is normally
available for the CA and can be easily recalled for the evaluation process. It is easy
to see that when a conduct impacts on a large amount of commerce in the relevant
markets, the implied transfer from consumers to manufacturers becomes
substantial. As mentioned above, for this reason the size of the relevant market is
likely to explain much of the variance in the estimated impact.
The number of cartel convictions, merger interventions (or challenges), and other antitrust
interventions are displayed in brackets. The number of challenged merger cases for the USDOJ
was collected from the Hart-Scott-Rodino Annual Reports for Fiscal Years 2007-10. The number
of cartel cases and the number of non-merger civil cases filed by the USDOJ was collected from
USDOJ statistics (http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/workload-statistics.html). The number of
challenged merger and non-merger interventions by the US FTC was collected from the FTC’s
Performance and Accountability Reports. For the EC, the number of interventions was collected
from EC merger statistics (http://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/statistics.pdf) and EC cartel
statistics (http://ec.europa.eu/competition/cartels/statistics/statistics.pdf) and the number of
abuse of dominance cases closed was collected from Global Competition Review reports.
14
15
Using an average overcharge of 20%-34% from Bolotova and Connor (2006).
16
The number of cases refers to the total number of criminal cases filed.
61
The more challenging part of the evaluation is to estimate the magnitude of price
increase from the investigated conduct and the length of time it would have
prevailed absent the intervention. Depending on the case type, CAs often use
assumed default values for these two factors in their evaluations. The following
briefly describes the methodologies used in the three jurisdictions. Unless
otherwise stated, the figures reported were collected from the respective CAs
methodology documents.17
Table 3.2 summarises the assumptions used in the evaluation of the impact of cartel
investigations. As for the OFT, these assumptions are only used if there is no hard
figure on overcharge thrown up during the investigation. On affected consumers
(i.e. size of market), it is often assumed that the cartel would only affect the
infringing parties’ turnover.18 Unlike the OFT, the other authorities assume that the
CA intervention leads to a 10 per cent reduction in price. As explained above, the
OFT has recently revised its default assumption to a reduction in price of 15 per
cent following intervention. This seems more in keeping with the wider empirical
evidence in the academic literature. Much of this evidence – meticulously collected
and organised in a meta-study by Bolotova and Connor (2006) – suggests that the
median cartel-induced price increase lies between 17 and 30 per cent.
Table 3.2
Assumptions used in cartel cases19
Assumed life
span (yrs)
Gain from cartel
Affected
consumers
EU
2009
5
EU
2010
1/3/6
USDOJ
2009
1
USDOJ
2010
1
OFT
2008-11
6
10%
Affected
market size
10%
Affected
market size
10%
Volume of
commerce
10%
Volume of
commerce
3.5
3.5
N/A
N/A
15%
Turnover
affected
goods
3.5
1.2
(EUR)
7.2
(EUR)
0.6
($)
0.05
($)
0.25
(£)
Social discount
21
rate
Estimated impact
(bn)
20
*
* Including cartels and other commercial agreements, and abuses of dominant position.
Sources: European Commission DGCOMP (2011a), the USDoJ (2012) and OFT (2011a).
17
Sources: European Commission DGCOMP (2011a), the USDoJ (2012) and OFT (2011a).
Of course the effects will typically will be much wider than just the sales of the cartel members,
hence this is likely to be an underestimate of the total impact.
18
19
Among other countries, the NMa assumes a 10 per cent overcharge.
20
10% before 2010.
21
This allows a discounting of future estimated cartel gains.
62
The assumptions on the expected future life-span of cartels show much wider
dispersion, not least probably because of the significantly smaller amount of
research that has been done on this matter. It seems tempting to rely on empirical
studies of cartel duration such as Block, Nold et al. (1981) and Levenstein and
Suslow (2006). However, these studies were conducted on cartels that were
detected, which are likely to be different from undetected ones and the assumption
here has to be made on the cartel remaining undetected. For this reason it may
seem more reasonable to turn to what economic theory has to offer on the matter.
Works on the incentives created by leniency programmes have shown that it is the
less stable cartels that are more likely to apply for leniency.22 For these cartels it
would be reasonable to assume a shorter future life-span (i.e. that the cartel would
not have survived much longer even absent intervention). In other cases however
the CA detects cartels ex officio. Block et al. (1981) argue that the detection
probability in ex-officio cases increases with mark-ups. The rationale behind this is
that higher mark-ups are more likely to be spotted by customers or the CA, and
therefore there is a higher chance of the ex-officio triggering of investigations. As
higher mark-up cartels are likely to be more stable, a longer life-span assumption
may be more fitting in these cases. It therefore seems more appropriate to apply a
case sensitive assumption for the expected duration of the cartel absent
intervention. For example Harrington (2008) shows that the quality of leniency
programmes (i.e. the amount of immunity leniency programmes award to firms)
has an effect on how stable cartels are. This would suggest that different
assumptions should apply depending on the given on the rigour of the given
competition regime. Other characteristics, such as the type of the industry, specific
market conditions, and entry conditions also have an impact on cartel stability.
Given this potential heterogeneity, a case-dependent approach recently adapted by
the EC would seem to be most in line with economic theory. 23
In merger cases, as for the OFT, simulation is fairly often used to estimate how prices,
demand, and market shares might have changed had the merger gone ahead absent
the CA’s intervention. When the price impact of a merger was estimated during the
merger procedure this can be (and often is) used in impact evaluation. In other
cases default assumptions are made on the price impact, which are summarised in
Table 3.3.24 Previously the EC assumed that the future customer savings resulting
22
See Harrington (2008) for a discussion on this together with relevant references.
The EC classifies cartels (based on economic theory and evidence) into three categories:
"unsustainable", "fairly sustainable" "very sustainable", and assumes a future cartel life of 1, 3,
and 6 years respectively.
23
Amongst some of the other jurisdictions, in the Netherlands the NMa uses the turnover of the
relevant firms as a basis and assumes a one per cent price increase (Kemp and Sinderen (2008)).
In Portugal, the PCA assumes mergers to lead to a 5.3 per cent price increase, which will last for
two years and is discounted at 3.5 per cent (Weinberg (2007)). The Competition Commission
(CC) in the UK – being a Phase II body – has more information available on the cases it looks at,
therefore it does not adopt a single approach in each case, rather, it seeks to capture what the
team conducting that investigation believed was the likely effect of the merger.
24
63
from corrective merger decisions corresponds to 10 per cent of the size of the
relevant market(s) on which the concentration would have significantly impeded
effective competition. This has now been changed to a practice whereby price
effects are simulated on a case-by-case basis.
Table 3.3
Assumptions used in merger cases
EU2009
(bn eurs)
N/A
EU2010
(bn eurs)
Size of relevant
market
USFTC2010
(bn $)
Volume of
commerce
USDOJ2010
(bn $)
Volume of
commerce
Price effect
N/A
Simulated
1%
1%
Consumer
impact
10% of
relevant
market
size
1
N/A
N/A
N/A
OFT200811(£bn)
Turnover
of affected
goods
Average of
simulated
N/A
Significant/high/very
high
2
1
2
4.2-6.3
0.59
0.19
Affected
consumers
Duration of
price impact
(yrs)
Estimated
impact
5.6
*
0.36
* Merger and other civil antitrust combined.
Sources: European Commission DGCOMP (2011a), the USDoJ (2012) and OFT (2011a).
The suitability of these methods is more difficult to assess than in the case of cartels.
Firstly, in merger cases the CA has to decide ex-ante whether a merger is
anticompetitive and to find a suitable intervention. This means that impact
estimates would need to establish if the CA had been right to intervene in the first
place. It is unlikely that any CA would admit to a wrongful intervention in their
accountability reports, therefore, absent intervention, the intervened mergers in the
evaluation are always assumed to have a negative impact. Secondly, price increase
estimates depend largely on the severity of the merger control regime. In a lax
regime, only cartels with large and positive price effects are intervened, therefore
the average estimated price impact of intervened mergers will be larger than with a
stricter CA.25 Thirdly, it is not clear what value, if any, should be given to mergers
that the CA correctly did not intervene (i.e. mergers with a negative price change).
In the academic literature, there are some studies that investigate the price impact
of intervened US mergers.26 Ashenfelter and Hosken (2008) for example looked at
five selected cases and found estimated price increases to be between 3 and 7 per
cent. In earlier studies Werden et al. (1991) reported a 5.6 per cent price increase,
and Borenstein (1990) estimated a 9.5 per cent average increase. The literature is
much scarcer for other jurisdictions. However, even if we had a more
comprehensive idea about the average price impact of mergers, its use as a best
25
Carlton (2009) also discusses this possibility.
26
Weinberg (2007) surveys the relevant US literature.
64
practice or default assumption in this context could be questioned for various
reasons. For example, as mentioned above, a systematic bias in the CAs decision
making might mean that mergers with small positive price effects (when the CA is
too lax) or mergers with small negative price changes (when the CA is too strict) are
not picked up by the CA and hence would not appear in the evaluation. Relying on
an average merger price effect assumption would therefore also require some
knowledge on whether the CA is too lax or too strict. Mergers are also likely to
have very different price effects depending on the economic environment and
therefore assumptions based on estimates in one jurisdiction may lead to biased
evaluations in the other.
For these reasons it seems most reasonable for the evaluation of mergers to rely,
whenever is possible, on a case-by-case approach and use price-effect figures from
the simulations conducted during the investigation. Simulations are becoming
more common, especially in the assessment of those mergers that the CA judges to
be potentially more harmful and an estimated price effect would therefore be
available from the investigation. In more simple cases the impact of the merger is
more likely to be closer to zero and therefore excluding them from evaluations
(because there is no case-specific price-impact estimate) would only have a
marginal effect on the estimated aggregate impact of merger control. A variation of
this approach is used by the OFT, where, if simulation is not appropriate for the
case, consumer savings as a proportion of turnover are assumed to be equal to the
mean lower bound of the same ratio across all simulated mergers over the previous
three years.
The assumption on the duration of the merger-generated price impact shows more
convergence (being either one or two years). On the lower bound, as Davies (2010)
points out, it seems unlikely that a CA would choose to intervene if it believed that
post-merger self-correction within the market would occur within the following
one or two years. On the upper bound, the case-by-case approach used by the EC
seems appropriate. This method categorises all cases into one of three groups:
‚significant‛, ‚high‛ and ‚very high‛ and assigns them duration period in years as
the minimum time it would take to restore competition to its pre-merger state.
Turning to abuse of dominance cases, as Werden (2008) points out, these pose
arguably the greatest challenges for assessment (see section 1.5 above). Similarly to
other case types, if case-specific information is not available, assumptions are made
about the default price rise, and the duration of the infringement (see Table 3.2).
The lack of empirical IO work on abuse of dominance cases makes it difficult to
assess these assumptions.
In addition, some of the CAs also conduct an assessment of other activities such as
consumer protection, or advocacy. As described above, the OFT compares the preand post-intervention number of consumer complaints, and a reduction in the
number of complaints is converted into a financial estimate of avoided consumer
65
detriment by valuing each complaint at a proportion of the purchase value.27 As a
performance measure, the FTC reports the number of consumer complaints and the
percentage of the FTC’s consumer protection law enforcement actions that target
the subject of consumer complaints to the FTC. Other methods such as consumer
satisfaction surveys are also applied in other countries.
Table 3.4
Assumptions used in other antitrust (non-cartel) cases
Affected
consumers
Price effect
Consumer impact
Duration of price
impact (yrs)
Estimated impact
(bn)
EU
2009
N/A
EU
2010
N/A
USFTC
2010
Volume of
commerce
USDOJ
2010
Volume of
commerce
N/A
10% of
relevant
market
1
N/A
10% of
relevant
market
1
1%
N/A
1%
N/A
2
1
2
(EUR)
0
(EUR)
0.52
($)
0.19
($)
OFT
2008-11
Turnover
affected
goods
28
15%
N/A
6
*
* Merger and other civil antitrust combined.
** Including cartels and other commercial agreements, and abuses of dominant position.
Sources: European Commission DGCOMP (2011a), the USDOJ (2012) and OFT (2011a).
This is problematic if the number of complaints increases due to increased consumer
awareness.
27
28
5% before 2010.
0.25
(£)
**
66
4
Conceptual Issues in Accountability Evaluations
Some general issues arise from the above discussion. Firstly, some of the figures
reported above show that estimates are very sensitive to the assumptions used. A
case-by-case approach would therefore be desirable when possible. For the
remaining cases, where default assumptions are made, it would be desirable if
there was theoretically and evidence-based common practice. This would allow a
better comparison of estimates both over time (say to inspect the effect of a policy
change) and cross-jurisdiction.
Although evaluations are becoming increasingly more sophisticated, they usually
emphasise only the price effects of interventions – the price increases avoided as a
result of interventions, taking into account the size of the affected market. Of
course, it is to be hoped that the total benefits should extend beyond just price and
include the effects on quality, choice and innovation, but these are usually very
difficult to measure accurately. For this reason, it is reasonable to interpret the
results of these evaluations as typically conservative estimates. Some activities of
the CA are also excluded, such as competition advocacy, or consumer education.
The tendency for producing conservative estimates seems justified as a definitive
measure of ex-post impact is often impossible (for example, we will never know
what would have happened had a prohibited merger not been prohibited). Also,
interventions may have an impact well into the very long-term and onto wider
socio-economic factors, and the cost of conducting a comprehensive ex-post
evaluation across all cases would be disproportionately large. These longer-term
and wider effects are discussed later in the report.
Although practicability issues may limit the scope of impact evaluations and make
it difficult to include longer-term or wider impacts, there are some areas which
seem unjustifiably omitted from these reports. Impact evaluations only look at
cases where the CA had decided to intervene and therefore exclude those cases
where there was no intervention. For example in mergers, no impact is associated
with mergers that the CA rightly authorised without intervention. This may be
particularly important for cleared efficiency-enhancing mergers, where the impact
on consumer benefits might be increased by some measure of the positive impact
that arises from the unconditional approval of the merger. Cases where parties
settle before the CA reaches a final decision are also excluded from these
evaluations. These settlements are clearly the result of effective enforcement and
should therefore be taken in to account, for example as a result of the deterrent
effect of the CA’s work.
Because of the size-difference in the relevant affected markets across cases, the
aggregate savings computed may be very sensitive to one or two extreme
observations. Also, potential errors in particular cases could make year-to-year
fluctuations volatile. As Davies (2010) argues, using moving-averages helps to
smooth impact estimates over the years. In the UK both the OFT and the CC applies
67
rolling-average figures, and so does the Netherlands Competition Authority
(NMa).
When impact estimates are acquired for accountability reasons, an important
source of bias could be caused by the fact that given finite resources, coupled with a
need to substantiate its impact, it is rational for any CA to pursue the ‘easy options’
in its enforcement activities; i.e. to cherry pick easier cases at the expense of more
difficult cases (for which the probability of ‘success’ is lower or where there is
greater uncertainty). A related danger is highlighted by Neven and Zengler (2008),
who suggest that the evaluation programme itself may introduce an additional
motive for distortionary discretion in CA conduct: ‚Faced with simplistic
assessment, authorities may be tempted to be overly interventionist, to spend too
many resources and to ignore relevant information.‛ If evaluation is driven by
external accountability (to verify whether the CA delivers its objectives) and
especially if undertaken by the CA itself, the CA is prone to fall into the trap that is
also identified by Chang and Harrington (2010), i.e. CAs will not seek to maximise
deterrence, but focus on something that is observable/measurable (e.g. the
proportion of Art.102 cases that are won, or the number of cartels detected). This
can have important feedback effects, not just for evaluation, but also for success in
achieving the ultimate objectives of competition policy and in extreme cases even
bias decision-making. These reasons may justify, in some cases, the use of an
external auditor to conduct the assessment.
4.1
Unobserved impact of competition policy
As mentioned above, impact evaluations necessarily focus on only a selected part of
the total effect of competition policy and law enforcement. Some of the impacts are
not observed and are therefore not measurable, or at least, very difficult to estimate.
The impact estimates presented above therefore do not include the deterrent effect
of competition policy, or behaviour that remain undetected, or conducts that the
CA detects but decides not to investigate or intervene. Unless the evaluation
acknowledges how this selection process works, any impact estimate will be
inherently biased.29
Impact evaluations also typically ignore the possibility that there may be deterred
pro-competitive cases. Baker (2003) notes that he suspects the costs from deterred
pro-competitive activities not to exceed the direct costs (to the firms) of
enforcement. Although he does not go into further analysis, this statement seems
intuitively reasonable on the assumption that only those pro-competitive conducts
are deterred that are less profitable than the firm’s assessment of the expected cost
of litigation, implying that if a conduct is sufficiently pro-competitive, it is more
See section 8 below and Davies and Ormosi (2010) for more detail. Carlton (2009) also warns
about this in his discussion of measuring the average impact of merger control.
29
68
likely to take place. A statement like this would of course only hold true if the CA is
unbiased and free of hostility towards efficiency gains.30
To account for the deterrent effect of enforcement, one would need to be able to
measure deterrence. While this is still an area which defies definitive quantification,
there exists some work of interest, particularly where a competition policy index is
constructed from institutional, legal, and social factors that are expected from
economic and legal theory to deter certain types of behaviour. For example
Buccirossi et al. (2009b) created an index of a set of institutional and enforcement
features that are expected to have an impact on the level of sanctions incurred by
those who are convicted, the (perceived) probability of being detected and
convicted, and the (perceived) probability of being wrongly convicted or acquitted.
Using these types of indices allows an ordinal measurement of the levels of general
deterrence across countries.
A related issue arises regarding cases that the CA did not detect. For example
empirical works suggest that not more than a fifth of all cartels are detected (see
section 8.1 below) Should these forgone opportunities appear in impact evaluations
(for example as an opportunity cost)?
Although deterred cases are not observed, and therefore no specific estimates of the
deterrence effect are included in CAs’ aggregate evaluations, the OFT has
acknowledged this issue in its recent impact assessments (for example, (2011a,
p.24). To provide a suggestive ball-park figure for the magnitude of deterrent
effects, it uses the assumption that, for every investigated case, there are five other
cases which do not occur because they are deterred, and therefore the estimated
impact based on intervened cases are multiplied by five. The 5:1 multiplier is, of
course, highly speculative and is based on a survey conducted by Deloitte (2007) for
the OFT. In a subsequent survey by London Economics (2011), also commissioned
by the OFT and using a similar methodology, the evidence points, if anything, to a
significantly higher multiplier. However, whatever the value of the multiplier, the
line of reasoning requires the questionable assumption that deterred cases share the
same characteristics as intervened ones, which – according to economic theory – is
unlikely to be the case. Taking the example of cartels, economic theory implies that
more stable cartels are less likely to be deterred and detected.31 Therefore, any
estimate will ignore those cartels that are likely to be the most harmful. Similar
arguments could also be used for mergers. If mergers with high price-increasing
30
See Werden, Joskow et al. (1991) on the evolution of the treatment of efficiencies in antitrust.
Chang and Harrington (2010) argue that less stable cartels are more likely to apply for
leniency. If cartel investigations are triggered dominantly by leniency applications (in the EC 2/3
of the cartel investigations result from leniency) then the investigated cartels will be the less
stable ones.
31
69
effects are more likely to be deterred,32 then impact estimates based on investigated
cases only will be negatively biased.
Another seemingly simple way to get a grasp of the level of deterrence is to look at
how the number of cases changes over time. This leads to the problem that the
number of detected cases is an ambiguous indicator of deterrence, as an increased
number of observed cases could mean either an increase in the detection rate or a
decrease in the deterrence rate of enforcement, or both. A change in the number of
observed cases can only be meaningfully interpreted if, at the same time, the
change in detection rate is also known. This of course may not pose an
insurmountable problem in areas where the rate of detection is expected to be
constant, which is likely the case in merger control regimes with compulsory premerger notification rules. Barros, Clougherty et al. (2010) build on this feature when
they estimate the deterrent effect of merger policies. Otherwise, Ormosi (2011)
proposes a way to estimate how detection rate changes over time in anti-cartel
enforcement, which in turn could be used to make inferences on the rate of change
in deterrence. It may indeed be this latter category (the marginal impact of
competition policy on deterrence) where future work should focus, i.e. whether
additional Government spending increases deterrence.
We return to sample selection, detection and deterrence in the final chapter.
For example Barros, Clougherty et al. (2010) suggest that firms may reduce the restrictiveness
of their merger in order to increase the chances of approval.
32
70
5
Ex-post Evaluation by the Competition
Authorities
In the main, the evaluations described in the three previous chapters are ex-ante.
However, the CAs also undertake ex-post evaluation, usually on a more ad hoc
basis.
Ex-post evaluations can be loosely broken down into two main types. Qualitative
studies typically survey the market post intervention in an attempt to find out
whether the predictions at the time of the intervention have proven to be true or
not. These studies systematically examine how market entry and expansion
conditions changed in the years following intervention and assess whether the
predictions at the time of the decision turned out to be accurate. The other type
relies more on quantitative works by trying to establish causality between the
intervention and, for example, a change in the market price. In practice it is
common that if the evaluation is commissioned by the CA then a mixture of these
two types of method is used. The following are some illustrative examples.
The most notable examples, published and therefore in the public domain, is a
series of reviews for the UK, where the CC, the OFT and the relevant Government
Department have regularly conducted (or commissioned) retrospective merger
reviews, reflecting upon market developments following the merger interventions
(PricewaterhouseCoopers (2005); UK Competition Commission (2008); Deloitte
(2009), LEAR (2011)).
Various methodologies have been used for this purpose. For example the 2009
evaluation (see Chapter 7) used interviews with market participants, and
simulations, whereas a 2011 assessment chose to rely on DiD and a survey of
market actors. Follow-up questionnaires and/or interviews with the interested
parties and related firms often provide invaluable insights but are inevitably prone
to a number of potential limitations: low response rates, respondent bias, the parties
often have short corporate memories, and in their view, interventions can often be
overtaken by other subsequent and more important events. In a much earlier study,
Clarke et al. (1998) includes a number of examples of the latter. The OFT also
reviews (or commissions) two of its cases every year.33 These assessments involve a
post-event monitoring of market developments.34 The OFT and the CC also
regularly conduct an assessment of the impact of market studies.
For example, in 2011 it evaluated the impact of the 2001 abuse of dominance case against Napp
Pharmaceuticals (2011d), and the 2005 consumer enforcement case against Foxtons (2011e).
33
34
An OFT example (2007) is the impact assessment of the Payment Systems Task Force review.
71
A different type of exercise is when the survey focuses on the perception of
stakeholders regarding the CA’s practices in general. The purpose of these surveys
is typically to provide an objective measure of the experiences and the satisfaction
of stakeholders with the CA’s work. The surveyed stakeholders may include parties
to the given case, third party businesses, interested businesses, professional
advisors, or government bodies. Examples for this are given by the UK’s
Competition Commission (2009), and the EC (2010).
The EC commissions some of their evaluation work to external experts. Buccirossi
et al. (2006) for example use a combination of an event study and a survey to
examine whether the EC made the right decision in the Pirelli/BICC merger (see
Chapter 7). A recent example from the new Competition Commission of Mauritius
(CCM) (2011) examined the evolution of market price, the change in the market
structure and a calculation of possible savings to consumers following its
intervention in an abuse of dominance case (see Chapter 7).
Some studies have assessed the quality of CA decision-making by the frequency of
court appeals and/or the success rates in those appeals.35 For certain purposes this
may be a valuable extra source of (presumably well-informed and objective)
evaluation, but obvious limitations include the likelihood of selection bias, and the
fact that court decisions will sometimes involve judgement on the correctness of
legal process rather than economic substance. Although courts analyse cases expost, they typically rely only on information that had already been available at the
time of the CAs intervention. Bergman (2008) also points out that relying too much
on appeal success ratios may have an incentive effect (similar to what has been
discussed above), because CAs may become more interested in pursuing simple
cases or enforcing only against blatantly illegal conduct.
Certain high-profile annual reviews provide an alternative approach to ex-post
assessment, based on peer review evaluation of the performance of different CAs
around the world, e.g. the Global Competition Review and OECD country reviews.
These enable international comparisons over time at the aggregate level, but are
often based on subjective opinion rather than quantitative methodologies.
Some of the CAs have also conducted or commissioned case studies of the
successfulness of their enforcement toolkit. For example the success of merger
remedies has been analysed by the USFTC (1999), the EC (2005) and the UK CC
(2010).36 These evaluations look at whether past merger remedies were suitable to
remedy a competition problem.
Similarly to what has already been argued in the previous chapter, there is an
innate risk in the internal assessment of specific cases, which stems from the risk of
35
Bergman (2008) provides a brief survey of these and discusses their limitations in more detail.
36
See also an EC commissioned study by Davies and Lyons (2007) on merger remedies.
72
self-reporting bias, especially in cases still pending appeal, as the CA has a strong
incentive to report high consumer savings otherwise to avoid providing evidence
against their own case.37 Given the potential risk of this bias, third-party
evaluations may be preferred in some circumstances.38
37
Bergman (2008) also emphasises this possibility.
38
A similar recommendation is given by Buccirossi, Ciari et al. (2006).
73
6
Evaluation Techniques: previous literature, pros
and cons
The next two chapters will focus more specifically on the alternative techniques
which might be used to evaluate the impact of a particular intervention for a
particular case. This chapter first defines the three main classes of methodologies:
simulation, event studies and differences-in-differences. These were first
introduced briefly in section 1.3, and they were referred to, in passing, in the
previous chapters. This chapter now provides more extensive definitions, surveys
of the literatures in which the methodologies have been used, and discusses their
‘pros’ and ‘cons’, i.e. advantages and disadvantages. The next chapter then
provides an overview of six specific case studies in which they have been
employed, in order to illustrate the types of data they require, and theoretical and
empirical models on which they might be based.
6.1
Simulation and structural models
By simulation, we refer to evaluation based on the following three stages:
(i)
An explicit formal modelling of the nature of competition in the market (the
nature of oligopoly, homogenous or differentiated products, existence of
capacity constraints, unilateral or coordinated action, market symmetry,
etc.). This stage often involves a structural model derived from a game
theoretic perspective, coupled with a particular model of the demand
system, e.g. logit, nested logit or random utility.
(ii)
Calibrating the model with real world information derived from direct
observation, or from full-blown econometric estimation of the demand
system to acquire estimates of model parameters (e.g. existing market
shares, prices and extraneous estimates of demand elasticities).39
(iii)
Using the model to assess how the equilibrium would change with and
without an event/intervention (for example comparing the pre-merger
equilibrium with the hypothetical non-intervened equilibrium40).
By substitution of these parameters into the equilibrium conditions derived in stage 1, one can
then recover (i.e. solve for) other, unknown, parameters, such as firms’ marginal costs.
39
In principle, one might also simulate a switch in the prevailing behaviour of firms as a
consequence of the merger; for example, if it is suspected that the merger would result in a
coordinated effect between merging and non-merging firms, one could compute alternative
collusive post-merger equilibria. Rather more difficult are the possibilities that firms might want
to reposition their products, or where the potential for new entry becomes important.
40
74
In principle, simulation may be either ex-ante or ex-post, but most applications are
ex-ante in the sense that they are based on data available at the time of the
intervention – even if they are actually conducted retrospectively.
6.1.1 Previous literature
The early development of simulation was firmly rooted in the academic literature
and some of the seminal contributions include Farrell and Shapiro (1990), Werden
and Froeb (1994), Hausman and Leonard (1997), Werden (2000) and Nevo (2000).
These references all relate to merger simulation which is overwhelmingly the most
common area of application. Fairly comprehensive surveys are provided by Davies
and Lyons (2007), Budzinski and Ruhmer (2010) and Buccirossi et al. (2006).
Simulation is far less frequently applied in evaluating the effects of abuse of
dominance or in cartel interventions, but see Verboven and Van Dijk (2009).
Increasingly over the last 20 years, simulation has featured in specific merger
investigation by the CAs and advisers to the parties. Again, these are well
documented in the literature – fairly comprehensively, for example by Budzinski
and Ruhmer (2010), including: Interstate Bakeries/Continental Baking (US 1995),
Kimberley-Clark/Scott (US 1996), Volvo/Scania (EU 1999), Lagardere/Natexis/VUP
(EU 2003), Nuon/Reliant (NMa Netherlands 2003), Oracle/PeopleSoft (EU and US
2004). These and other cases led to subsequent seminal simulation papers in the
academic literature including Pinske and Slade (2004), Ivaldi and Verboven (2005),
and Peters (2006).
6.1.2 Pros and cons
The major strength of the simulation approach is the explicit use of theory to
identify the counterfactual. This facilitates the ‘joining-up’ of the analysis
undertaken at the time of the intervention with any subsequent evaluation of the
effects of the policy, and, in turn, provides a clear opportunity for evaluating the
assumptions made at the time of the intervention.
However, as is well documented, simulation is very sensitive to modelling
assumptions. Sometimes this is a strength, e.g. in revealing how sensitive
predictions are to the precise nature of the counterfactual, but sometimes this
sensitivity is unhelpful, deriving from alternative specifications between which
there are no strong theoretical reasons to choose, e.g. the functional form of the
demand curve. These qualifications are well documented elsewhere (see for
example Buccirossi et al. (2006)).
Equally important, simulation is better suited for some types of oligopoly models
(and therefore markets) than others. The trusted and well-tried workhorses are the
Cournot homogeneous product model, and logit type models of product
75
differentiation. These may be appropriate for industries which are either
homogeneous products, with or without capacity constraints, or with horizontally
differentiated products. In such industries an emphasis on price and quantity may
be more appropriate. However, where products are vertically differentiated and
competition is effected more through product quality and innovation, these models
are typically incapable of describing the competitive process. Other aspects which
are difficult, if not always impossible, to model completely satisfactorily are: (i)
possible changes in conduct post-merger (coordinated effects), (ii) buyer power,
and (iii) bidding markets (which is still in its infancy). This raises the strong
likelihood that evaluation based on simulation is heavily skewed towards certain
types of markets, potentially leading to a sample selection bias.
Another potential source of selection bias derives from the heavy demands on data.
Many of the seminal studies are based on high quality disaggregated datasets
constructed from scanner sources; but, of course, these are typically drawn from a
relatively small set of consumer good products (often sold through supermarkets).
Finally, there is mixed evidence on how well simulation predicts actual outcomes.
Ashenfelter and Hosken (2008, p.36) summarise on this count by suggesting that
‚careful evaluation of their effectiveness seems long overdue‛.
6.1.3 Back of the envelope (simple) simulation
As mentioned, full-fledged simulation is extremely demanding of data and research
time. Faced with this, CAs in their own evaluation exercises often employ
simplified versions of simulation models (the only viable option if the CA is to
evaluate a range of mergers investigated in a given year). Typically, most of their
effort is directed to those mergers where the product is homogeneous, and can be
reasonably described by the Cournot model, or simple models of differentiation. In
order to calibrate these, extraneous estimates of demand elasticities are required,
but there is often a scarcity of good estimates. In these circumstances, Werden
(2008) reports that the US typically employs a range of 1 to 1.5 for the aggregate
industry demand elasticity, but is not obvious whether this is a reasonable ball-park
range. Such inelastic demand will inevitably lead to high predicted price increases.
As noted by Bergman (2008, p.394) ‚There exist amazingly few econometric studies
of the price effects of mergers, considering the economic importance of mergers and
given that merger effects is a topic that is well suited for this type of quantitative
analysis‛. Below, we discuss Connor’s painstaking meta-analyses of cartels, but
there appears to be no equivalent for mergers. At the very least, there is an obvious
gap to be filled by a similar sort of meta-analysis of the industry demand price
elasticity – given its key role in most simulation.
76
6.2
Event studies
An event study draws on financial market data to measure the effect of an
economic event on the market valuation of a firm. If financial markets are efficient,
then the effect of any event on a firm’s discounted profits will be instantaneously
observable through the changes in the prices of its shares. The methodology entails
measuring any abnormal returns associated with an event (e.g. the announcement
of a merger). Abnormal returns are identified as the difference between the
observed movement in stock valuation and those that would have occurred absent
the event.
6.2.1 Previous literature
Event studies of mergers typically examine the effect of the announcements of the
merger and the CA’s decision (i.e. the type of intervention) on the valuation of the
merging firms and their rivals.41 For Europe, Duso et al. (2007) apply the
methodology to a sample of 151 mergers, 1990-2002, and show that, for at least half
of them, rival firms benefit after the merger is announced. According to theory,
mergers will benefit rivals only if they are price raising, i.e. anticompetitive. Duso et
al. (2011) subsequently focus on the effects of the Commission’s decisions (merger
remedies) and find that, on average, remedies seem to be only partially capable of
reversing announcement abnormal returns – especially for Phase 2 decisions. For
Australia, Diepold, Feinberg et al. (2006) apply the methodology to 50 mergers
handled by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission between 19962003, and find, for example, that the CA did not intervene in any of the mergers
which the event study suggested to be pro-competitive, i.e. consistency between the
CA and the financial markets. The methodology has also often been applied to
specific case studies, for example by Simpson and Hosken (1998) for four FTC
investigations of retail mergers between 1984 and 1993, and Warren-Boulton and
Dalkir (2001) for the Staples – Office Depot merger.
Event studies on cartels typically examine the impact of dawn raids and the
subsequent CA decisions, for example Langus and Motta (2010) for EC cartel
enforcement, and Bosch and Eckard (1991) for US DoJ decisions. Lübbers (2009)
studied the effect of cartelisation (a coal syndicate) in Germany, 1893-1913, where
the events analysed were the foundation of the syndicate and two major
modifications to the original contract. Applications of the methodology to cases of
monopoly abuse are somewhat less frequent, but examples for specific cases
include Bittlingmayer and Hazlett (2000) for Microsoft, and Sidak (2003) for
WorldCom. In a recent novel application of the approach, Broek et al. (2012) study a
sample of 66 Dutch antitrust investigations (including cartels). Their approach
Eckbo (1985) is an early discussion of how the effects on rivals’ valuation provides important
additional information.
41
77
entails decomposing the estimated value loss to the firms into three parts: (i) the
penalty itself, (ii) an estimate of future lost rents due to the assumed future removal
of the overcharge, and (iii) the ‘reputation loss’. The latter reflects the loss in future
rents because, in the light of the prosecution, the firm’s investors, customers and
suppliers revise ‘the terms of trade with which they do business with the firm’
(Broek et al. (2012, p.11)). This is estimated to account for one third of the overall
lost value. While this particular quantification must be very approximate, (being
derived as a residual, and therefore sensitive to inevitable errors in quantifying the
overcharge in component (ii)), methodologically this is an interesting idea on how
to interpret the estimated magnitudes of lost value from event studies.
More generally, Carletti et al. (2011) analyse the impact of the introduction, or
modification in competition laws in 18 jurisdictions.42 Other related subjects where
event studies have been used include private antitrust litigation (Bizjak and Coles,
1995) and the effects of entry (Whinston and Collins, 1992). Cichello and Lamdin
(2006) provide a fairly comprehensive survey across all areas of policy, and present
a more complete list of references.
6.2.2 Pros and cons
Central to the event study is the assumed rationality of markets, the efficient
market hypothesis (EMH), according to which share-prices instantly reflect the
value to investors of all the relevant information available to them. It builds upon
information that is generated by the interaction between a large number of selfinterested, independent, rational market agents. This information can then be
thought of as the best estimate, given the set of all available information.
If the EMH holds, then the change in the market’s valuation of a company will
always reflect an unbiased estimate which is both objective and quick. This
therefore enables a quicker assessment than from using more direct measures such
as product prices. The methodology may be particularly attractive to a CA as it
tackles the issue of information asymmetry between itself and the firms involved in
the event. This makes event studies more appealing than the analysis of accounting
data, which typically suffers from the potential bias that such information is
produced by the interested parties. It is also argued that event studies are
Other examples of measuring the effect of regulatory change, although not for competition
laws, include: Becher (2009), who looks at the effect of US interstate deregulation in the banking
sector; and Prager (1989), who examines the effect of the Interstate Commerce Act in the railroad
industry. A major problem with using event studies to measure the impact of regulatory changes
is the definition of the event window. Regulatory changes are lengthy procedures, typically
starting with drafting at administrative level, before the proposal is carried on to parliamentary
committees, brought to the chamber floor, and finally approved by the parliament. During this
process, information about the proposal is often made public. As the content of the legislative
draft may continuously evolve, it is hard to define an appropriate event window.
42
78
undemanding of data – the necessary data are easily accessible for listed firms (but
see below).
However, the plausibility of the EMH assumption is open to question, and some
commentators are sceptical. Werden (2008) suggests that the presumption that ‘the
instant analysis of uninformed investors is more accurate than the painstaking
work of enforcement agencies with access to confidential documents and data’ is
not supported by evidence.43
Mergers are the main area of competition policy where event studies have been
used. Table 6.1 summarises how each of the three constituent events are expected to
change the merging parties’ market value. At each stage, there is the potential for
ambiguity. For example an increase in valuation of the merging parties may reflect
either pro-competitive effects (efficiency gains), or anticompetitive effects
(exclusion, dominance, or collusion). Duso et al. (2007) argue that this ambiguity
can be resolved by observing the change in the valuation of rival firms. According
to most static oligopoly models, horizontal mergers will result in a higher product
price unless there are offsetting efficiency gains; while the former will also benefit
rivals, the latter will not. However, as the final row shows, the ambiguity does not
vanish completely. For example, although an observed negative change in the
rivals’ valuation may reveal pro-competitive (efficiency) expectations, it may also
indicate anticompetitive (exclusion) effects.
Table 6.1
Expected effects of a (horizontal) merger on merging firms’ and
rivals’ asset values
Source of post-merger
gains
Effect on:
Dominance or collusion
Efficiency
Exclusion
Merger proposal
Merging
firms
+
+
+
Rivals
+
–
–
Announcement of
investigation
Merging
Rivals
firms
–
–
–
+
–
+
Merger clearance
Merging
firms
+
+
+
Rivals
44
+
45
–
–
Source: Davies and Ormosi (2010)
There is also the possibility that the merger may be interpreted as a signal that
other firms in the same market will engage in merger activities in the near future,46
43
See also Malkiel (2003) for a more general criticism of EMH.
The situation would be different for vertical mergers, which can potentially have foreclosure
effects, and would therefore result in negative abnormal returns.
44
45
Assuming that competitors cannot free-ride on merger generated efficiencies.
Cox and Portes (1998) claim that was the case in the merger of SBC Communications and
Pacific Telesis Group.
46
79
which would increase the market valuation of rivals, resulting in the same sign of
change as with collusive and/or dominant outcomes. Although Da Graca (2006)
proposes a method for eliminating simultaneity biases, this still remains an underexplored issue. A further criticism is that the methodology does not separate out
the market’s anticipation of the CA’s eventual decision, therefore its reaction to an
‘antitrust event’ may equally be explained by the market updating its beliefs about
a particular antitrust decision, once the uncertainty about the merger investigation
is resolved. Duso et al. (2010) address this problem by using observable merger
characteristics to estimate the probability of a particular decision and correct the
average abnormal returns accordingly.
The pros and cons are similar for assessing cartel enforcement. However, in this
case (characterised by a higher level of CA secrecy, in order to ensure the success of
the investigation), there is more chance that the first event (typically in the form of a
dawn-raid) will actually be ‘unanticipated news’ to the market. Also, the theoretical
expectations are less ambiguous. The effect of news of the investigation and the
ultimate decision nearly unambiguously reduce the valuation of the parties. The
one exception is when insufficient sanctions are announced. In this case the
negative effect stemming from the elimination of cartel profit may be mitigated by a
smaller than expected fine.
An obvious question in general is how well event studies predict actual outcomes.
For mergers, Duso et al. (2010) compare the results of an event study with an expost analysis of balance sheet profits. They find that in some cases the abnormal
returns measured in event studies are positively and significantly correlated with
the ex-post measured profitability of the same mergers. This provides some
affirmative evidence, but further, and possibly deeper, statistical analysis is
required before any definite conclusions can be drawn on this.47
Finally, in spite of the general presumption that event studies are easy-to-use and
data are easily accessed from financial databases, there will be many circumstances
when appropriate data are not available. It is, of course, a necessary condition that
the parties and their rivals are all quoted on the stock market, but this is often not
the case, especially in markets where firms are small and rivals are scarce.
Moreover, very often the parties are large conglomerates and/or multinationals,
and the market concerned may constitute of only a small part of its aggregate
activities. Where this is the case, it can often prove difficult to identify any effect on
For example when calculating the ex-post profit effect of the merger, the counterfactual used is
the median firm in the same market minus the effective rivals. The authors assume that these
firms are not strongly affected by the merger, but this assumption needs more evidence
especially for large mergers, which may affect the profit figures of other – not directly competing
– firms in the market. The main worry however is that their results in general show that the stock
market reaction is positively correlated with the ex-post development of profit typically in cases
where a longer event-window is used. This raises doubts whether the stock market reaction is
actually a reaction to the merger or it picks up other confounding effects as well.
47
80
the firm’s valuation resulting from an event in a small market in a particular
country. Some of these practical difficulties are cited by inter alia Buccirossi et al.
(2006, p.187-8). A specific example is provided by Beverley (2008) who attempts to
apply the methodology to a sample of nine UK Competition Commission merger
inquiries but is ultimately frustrated by an inability to locate sufficient competitors
with traded equities and merging parties for whom the market concerned accounts
for a sufficiently large proportion of their activities. For these reasons, it seems
likely that event studies applied across samples of mergers may suffer from an
inherent sample selection bias.
6.3
Difference-in-Differences
Difference-in-differences (DiD) methods belong to a broad category of
methodologies sometimes known (rather unhelpfully) as evaluation methods (see
Buccirossi et al., 2006), which also includes natural experiments and matching
methods. The basic idea is to evaluate ‘performance’ before and after an event (or
sometimes before, during and after) in the market concerned relative to
performance in another similar (control) market, unaffected by the event. The
standard DiD application is typically econometric, in which the performance
measure (usually product price) is tracked over time to include the pre- and postperiods in the treatment (e.g. merger) and compared against the same in the control
market, with the use of dummy variables.
DiD analysis is typically conducted ex-post. The time lag before it is undertaken
reflects a trade-off between choosing a sufficiently long post-event period to gain a
better grasp of long-term effects, and avoiding the choice of a time period which is
so long that it would compromise the chances of finding a practicable control to
emulate the counterfactual. There are also some instances of ex-ante DiD analyses,
for example for predicting the effect of cartel intervention (which presumes
overcharge is removed).
6.3.1 Previous literature
Examples of DiD for cartels include Symeonidis (2002), who assesses the impact of
the introduction of the 1956 Restrictive Trade Practices Act in the UK. Levenstein
and Suslow (2006) examined the impact of the 1982 United States’ Export Trading
Company Act by comparing manufacturing industries with and without export
cartel exemption.
Connor et al. (1998) attempted to measure the impact of 112 American hospital
mergers, using a database of around 3500 hospitals. Their method essentially
follows a DiD approach, where the treatment markets were those with mergers,
and the control was taken from the remaining set of markets.
81
There are few examples where DiD has been applied to abuse of dominance cases,
deterrence, or other effects of public intervention. An early equivalent is Shaw and
Simpson (1986), who analyse the erosion of market dominance in markets where
the UK Monopolies and Mergers Commission was active (markets not investigated
by the MMC were the control group). There are also some examples where DiD has
been used to assess the impact of other types of regulatory intervention. For
instance, Cooper, Gibbons et al. (2010) use a DiD estimator to test whether the
introduction of hospital competition in the English NHS in January 2006 has led to
increased efficiency.
6.3.2 Pros and cons
The difference-in-differences approach enjoys an (at least superficial) appeal that it
uses observed data from the relevant product market (i.e. what actually happens) in
comparison with a control, where the event does not occur. Thus the counterfactual
is not dependent on untestable, maybe restrictive, theoretical assumptions.
However, the other side to the coin is that the methodology is inevitably
atheoretical. Since much depends in evaluation on the nature of the counterfactual
this means that a key part of the methodology – identifying an appropriate control
group – is also atheoretical. As such, there is a danger that the choice of
counterfactual (control group) is constrained by ‘what is out there’, i.e. the best of a
set of alternatives, none of which is entirely appropriate. When choosing the control
market the ideal is that it is characterised by the same supply and demand shocks
as the treatment market, which makes it possible to filter out the net effect of the
analysed event by controlling for these supply and demand shocks. But Simpson
(2008) warns about the danger of this assumption, claiming that even the same
supply and demand shocks may influence prices differently in the two markets.
On a practical level, the control should have a sufficient number of members and
time observations to emulate the random variation which would occur in the
treatment group post intervention that is unrelated to the intervention itself. Most
research however just assumes that the only difference between the treatment and
the control groups is the treatment.48 Meyer (1995) identifies some of the limitations
of this approach, such as omitted variables, trends in outcomes, measurement error,
simultaneity, selection bias, omitted interactions, etc.
Although DiD is most typically applied as an ex-post tool for evaluating the effect
of mergers, this raises a – typically unanswered – question: if the chosen control
group is other non-merging rivals, then how does one allow for the possible
externalities that the merger has on those rivals? Tenn and Yun (2010) for example
See Buccirossi, Ciari et al. (2006) for a discussion of the selection bias which will occur if the set
of unobservable characteristics which affect the decision to merge also affect the performance of
the parties post-merger.
48
82
looked at the effect of US divestitures in the Johnson & Johnson/Pfizer acquisition.
Although the authors concede that their choice of control group (similar brands in
the same category) may mean that the treatment (divestitures) had an effect on the
control group, they claim that this does not raise serious concerns when simply
looking at whether divestitures had an effect at all on prices. We are not convinced
that this is indeed the case. Ashenfelter and Hosken (2008) examined the price
impact of five US mergers using a set of different control groups. In the event, their
preferred choice was private label products sold in the same industry. Their
rationale for this was that private labels are only weak substitutes, from the
consumer’s viewpoint, for the higher quality branded products affected by the
merger. At least to the current author, familiar with the UK supermarket industry,
this would seem to be highly contestable. There are similar doubts with Dobson
and Piga (2011), who use as controls airline routes from different but close airportpairs.
Overall, difficulties in identifying a satisfactory control must raise the worry that
DiD may only be useable for a fairly small sample of markets, and a sample which
may not be representative of the population as a whole.
6.3.3 Before and after
One of the most commonly used methods of evaluation is to conduct a simple
before and after comparison of, say, price. This is strictly not difference-indifferences since there is no control group. In effect the implication, which is often
only implicit, is that there is no need for a control, or that the default counterfactual
is one of merely the status quo: absent the merger or intervention, the market
would simply have performed identically before and after. Clearly, the results from
such a methodology should be interpreted with caution – at the least, one would
look for qualitative sources (e.g. interviews/questionnaires) to substantiate the
choice of a no-change counterfactual.
A slightly more sophisticated variation on this theme is to econometrically estimate
an equation including a simple dummy variable reflecting the effect of the
intervention, and adding other ‘control variables’ in the hope that they capture, and
control for, other exogenous changes in the market. However, this still requires the
assumption that the counterfactual is no change since the additional exogenous
explanatory can, at best, control for confounding factors which would otherwise
obscure what is the equivalent to no change after the event.
6.4
Choosing between methodologies
In effect, much of our discussion so far can be interpreted as questioning the nature
of the counterfactual assumptions employed by different methodologies – both in
83
specific cases, but also more generally – are some methodologies intrinsically more
counterfactual-aware than others?
Simulation, by its nature, places the choice of counterfactual conspicuously at
centre stage: a specific oligopoly model is selected, and this immediately reveals the
nature of the assumed counterfactual equilibrium. Similarly, it must be calibrated
transparently with key parameter estimates. A related issue was raised by Davis
and Garces (2009) who pointed out that, in merger simulation, typically the premerger equilibrium is used as counterfactual, which ignores the possibility that the
market was not in equilibrium pre-merger and the merger happened to get to
equilibrium. Sidak and Teece (2009) also warn about the sensitivity of analysis to
the choice of the counterfactual.49
In DiD, the control plays the role of the counterfactual – for example, what would
have happened in the UK, had retail price margins for books not been repealed might be captured by what actually happened over the same period in Germany,
where it was not repealed (Davies and Olczak (2008)). Here, the choice of
counterfactual is less theoretically driven, and the strength of the methodology
rests on whether there really is a control (with adequate data) which is sufficiently
similar. In practice, data expediency may sometimes distract attention from how
closely this condition is met.
While it is less common to think of the counterfactual in the typical event study,
implicitly it is still there – captured by whatever comparator share price index the
practitioner uses to compute abnormal returns. Here there is a trade-off between
using a general index, which is less likely to be sensitive to market-specific
exogenous events, and more customised sector-specific indexes, which may not be
truly independent of the event at issue.
An ideal approach for comparing the alternative evaluation methodologies would
be to assemble an ideally very large, random sample of cases, and attempt to apply
all the methodologies to all cases in the sample. This would help both in assessing
their relative practicabilities and in identifying any systematic differentials in their
estimates. While it is likely that some CAs and advising consultancies do
sometimes conduct parallel assessments during their conduct of a particular case
(experimenting simultaneously with, say, an event study and a simulation), these
do not appear in the published literature of course. More generally, attempting
such a task across a large sample of cases would be difficult, and, in the event, has
not occurred to date.
Another possible way of finding adequate counterfactuals could use some sort of
propensity score matching. For example for cartels, one could estimate the
In one example they cite, they argue that, when using a SSNIP test in periods of economic
downturn, the counterfactual for a proposed merger may be that prices that would otherwise
fallen would might be stabilised.
49
84
probability of being in a cartel (using a latent dependent variable and market and
firm specific independent variables) and match observations (from both treatment
and non-treatment) that produced similar probabilities. The non-treatment cases
that produced similar estimated probabilities could then be used as counterfactuals.
6.4.1 Comparing counterfactuals: cartels as a case study
In this sub-section, we attempt to illustrate some of the issues in choosing the ‘right’
counterfactual with the following example. We use an existing database on cartel
overcharge already in the public domain, constructed by Connor and various coauthors. Connor’s meta-analysis draws together the results from a large number of
primary studies, including 800 observations, taken from nearly 400 cartel episodes
across the world.
This is only a second best to an ideal dataset, because the overcharge estimate for
each cartel has been computed typically using only a single methodology – for very
few of the cartels do we have alternative estimates using different methodologies.
This means that relatively higher power matched sample tests are impossible, but
the sheer size of the sample should nevertheless reveal some reasonably
meaningful insights into the estimates generated by different methodologies.
The version of the database we use here is summarised in Bolotova and Connor
(2006). The main purpose of their paper was to examine the determinants of
overcharge, and the methodologies used to derive the estimates were merely a
minor side issue to be controlled for. For us here, this is the main focus of attention.
They classify the estimation methods used in the primary studies into eight broad
groups. Of these, we discard about 30% of cases which belong to three of the
groups since they do not correspond to any of our methodologies above.50 Three of
the retained categories (Table 6.2) correspond roughly to the component parts of
DiD: Price before (Price after) are comparisons between the within-cartel-period
price and the price immediately before (after) the cartel period, and Yardstick
competition are relative to prices in yardstick ‘analogous markets that were
believed to be free from cartelization’. The Price war method compares prices
within the lifetime of a cartel with prices under temporary cartel breakdown.
Finally, the Econometric category, is very broad based, but appears to include
estimates based on simulation-type methods.
Table 6.2 shows the proportions of cases in each category and our calculation of
their sample mean overcharge estimates.51 They fall within a broadly similar range
50
These groups were: ‘sundry/unknown’, ‘historical records’, and ‘cost calculations’.
C&B do not report these means directly in their paper, but we have recovered them from their
reported preliminary regression of overcharge solely against dummy variables for each category
– in that case, regression coefficients coincide with the sample mean values.
51
85
(23–45 per cent), but with an intriguing ranking – price wars being the highest and
price-after the lowest.
Table 6.2
Choice of counterfactual for estimating overcharge
%
Mean overcharge
Price before
33
29
Price after
11
23
Price war
2
45
Yardstick competition
11
39
Econometric
15
31
Source: Author’s calculations using data reported in Bolotova and Connor (2006)
A simple null hypothesis is that each sub-sample (i.e. for each methodology) is
randomly drawn from the same population distribution of overcharges (i.e. no
systematic tendency for specific methodologies to over- or under-estimate).
Abstracting from systematic measurement errors,52 if the null is rejected, this
implies some systematic difference between methodologies in how they measure
the counterfactual. In common with others working in this area, Connor and
Bolotova refer to the counterfactual as the ‘but for’ price. However, this is not
without ambiguity: is the ‘but for’ price the ‘competitive’ price or the market price
that would have obtained under a set of identical conditions (including market
structure) except for the existence of the cartel? Contrary to some discussion, the
correct answer would appear to be the latter and this leaves open the possibility
that a defendant might argue that damages should be only moderate because the
‘but for’ should be the tacitly collusive price.
To pursue this further, consider the relative magnitudes of the sample means in the
above Table 6.2.53 Suppose, merely for the sake of the argument, that the yardstick
method identifies the ‘competitive’ outcome as the counterfactual. If so, we know
that on average cartels set a price 39% higher than the competitive level. This then
allows us to interpret the counterfactuals identified in the three other categories as
follows:

during price wars the price falls to 45 per cent below the cartel price, i.e. 6
per cent below the competitive level.

the price before cartel is typically 10 per cent higher than the competitive
level

52
the price after cartel is typically 16 per cent higher than the competitive level
Or that the researchers’ choice of estimator is not independent of the actual cartel price.
For this purpose the ‘econometric’ category is discarded because it includes a heterogeneous
variety of implicit oligopoly models (counterfactuals) across papers.
53
86
Taken at face value, this implies the following typical time path for price. Before the
cartel, price starts from a supra-competitive level then rises during the cartel
period, before falling post-cartel. However, post-cartel, price remains at a supracompetitive level.54 On the other hand, in the typical price war price falls
substantially below the competitive level (implying harsher punishment than Nash
reversion).
Of course, this is very highly speculative – it is based on simplistic interpretation of
sample point estimates without attention to statistical significance. This is
deliberate because of doubts about the quality of at least some of the estimates in
Connor’s database. Ehmer and Rosati (2009) have re-worked this database to
exclude all estimates not meeting a variety of selection criteria, and this leads to a
drastic pruning in the sample. Future work is anticipated which will investigate
whether the estimates reported in OXERA (2009, p.90-92) are robust to such a
pruning, and whether or not they differ significantly.
Regarding post-cartel prices, Kovacic, Marshall et al. (2007) report that in the post-plea period
products with two conspirators continue to be priced as if the explicit conspiracy never stopped,
while products with three or four conspirators return to pre-conspiracy pricing, or lower, quite
quickly. Sabbatini (2008, p.501) concludes his study of Italian milk cartels by noting that cartels
may continue as ‘well-established’ rules post-detection. This possibility, that tacit collusion
might often survive cartel busts is also implied by Fonseca and Normann (2009). Harrington
(2004) raises a slightly different argument: the parties might moderate price reductions mindful
of the signal that this would send to the courts regarding the magnitude of the previous
overcharge. Regarding pre-cartel price, Harrington (2006) points to various instances where
cartel formation is preceded by a significant price decline, and suggests that this might be
accounted for by, variously, cost/demand shocks, entry and/or capacity expansion, and the
breakdown of tacit collusion. However, as Harrington notes, this question has so far attracted
little or no theoretical examination.
54
87
7
Example Case Studies of Evaluation
Methodologies
The purpose of this section is to present six selected case studies to illustrate the
different methodologies described above. For each one, we describe the case itself,
the evaluation methodology and the data and results. We then point to the key
issues, problems and reservations, and discuss the choice of counterfactual. The
cases have been selected so as to include two examples each of differences-indifferences, event studies and simulation, we have also ensured a mix of mergers,
cartels and monopoly abuse, and the authors include academics, consultants and
competition authorities.
7.1
Case 1: Two UK Mergers (difference-in-differences)
This first example case study was a retrospective one – actually involving two quite
separate merger cases. It was conducted by the LEAR consultancy (Buccirossi et al,
2011) and commissioned by the UK’s Competition Commission (CC). The purpose
was to evaluate the quality of the CC’s decision-making, assumptions and analysis,
with these two particular mergers chosen as illustrative examples, rather than
because of any specific significance of the mergers themselves. Their focus was on
the effects of a merger on price, using the difference-in-differences methodology
applied within a regression framework, which also included other explanatory
variables to further control for confounding factors.
GAME/Gamestation
The GAME/Gamestation merger was a merger between two specialist retailers of
video games in the UK, and analysis was conducted for both ‘mint’ (brand new)
and ‘pre-owned’ games because there had been controversy in the original
investigation as to whether these belonged to the same market, or formed separate
markets. In a first stage, LEAR conducted a simple before-after analysis of national
average prices, and in a second stage a difference-in-differences analysis using the
merging parties as the treatment group and their competitors as the control group.
The data were for the prices of about 200 different games sold in 9 different retailers
both before and after the merger. The pre-merger data were available from the CC’s
original investigation and the post-merger prices were collected in a survey
conducted by LEAR itself.
Their main findings were that (i) there was a reduction in the general level of prices
in the years following the merger, and (ii) this downward trend was more marked
for the merging parties than for the market as a whole. On this basis, LEAR
concluded that the CC had made the correct decision in not intervening in the
merger, and that this was probably circumstantial evidence that not only did the
88
merger not enhance market power, but also it appears to have had an efficiency
enhancing effect.
Waterstone’s/Ottakars
The Waterstone’s/Ottkars merger was a merger between two specialist ‘High Street’
book retailers in the UK. Again, the focus was on price although ideally measures
of quality, such as range of titles and quality of service would also have been
examined. As a first step, designed to establish the geographic dimension of the
market, LEAR conducted an analysis of the variability in price across the parties’
stores, but this was inconclusive. As a second step, it assembled two different
datasets – one at the individual store level for Waterstone’s (200 titles across 60
different stores) and the other at the national level, designed to establish the effect
of concentration both locally and nationally. Here, there was both a before- and
after-merger dimension. At the local level, the control was achieved by comparing
stores where there was an overlap between the parties pre-merger, against those
where there was not. At the national level, the control was the parties’ main rivals.
In both cases, the methodology suggested that the merger had no price raising
consequences. However, this was possibly due to an exogenous toughening in
competition at the time due to the growth of the internet sellers (notably Amazon)
and sales of books by the giant UK grocery supermarkets.
These two cases help illustrate some more generic features of the difference-indifferences methodology. First, the demands on data (and therefore time and
financially) are often intense – many of the most successful previous applications
have involved retail markets with a local as well as national dimension which adds
an additional potential source of variability. It also helps considerably if the predata were already collected and available from the original investigation – as they
were here. However, even in these two data-rich examples, it proved impossible for
a very able team who were not overly time/cost constrained to undertake any tests
of the key service-quality dimension.
The choice and availability of alternative counterfactuals is also a key issue. In this
case, as in many other local retail cases, the existence of some local markets where
only one of the parties was present pre-merger is extremely valuable – an attempt
to establish what would happen if two competitors become only one is facilitated if
we can already observe some markets where this is only one. On the other hand,
the use of competitors’ prices as a control is potentially problematic. In most
oligopoly models, the equilibrium response by the outsiders to a merger is rarely
zero, and in general it will be optimal for rivals to raise their prices post-merger. If
so, interpreting rivals’ prices as indicative of what would have happened had the
merger not occurred is questionable.
89
7.2
Case 2: Cheese in Mauritius (back-of-envelope difference-indifferences)
This case has been chosen as a very recent example of an in-house ex-post impact
evaluation by a young competition authority - the Competition Commission of
Mauritius (CCM) (2011) and its intervention in 2010 against an abuse of monopoly.
The abuse was the practice of offering retroactive rebates on Kraft branded block
processed cheddar cheese in exchange for supermarket premium shelf space, not
only for Kraft’s cheese but also for other Kraft-branded products, including
chocolates, biscuits and powdered juice. The evaluation was conducted unusually
soon, only one year, after the CCM’s intervention. Typically, studies only tend to be
conducted a number of years after in order that more post-intervention data are
available. However, as pointed out by CCM, this was two years after the
investigation-launch and they judged that the impact was beginning to be felt even
whilst the investigation was underway. The assessment examined price and the
change in market structure. The data used were collected from various
governmental institutions as well as the market players themselves.
It found that, post-intervention, two new brands entered, driving the HHI index
down from 8,200 to less than 5,000. In itself, this was considered to be a positive
impact since CCM viewed the offending practice to be exclusionary and it saw as
its objective the reduction of barriers to entry. It also found that the average price of
the two incumbents (Kraft and Chesdale) increased by 6 per cent in the postintervention year compared to an annual average increase for the three years preintervention of 16.5 per cent. In addition, following the entry of the two new
brands, the average price of the two incumbents actually fell by 4.5 per cent; and
there was a significant drop in the price of block processed cheddar cheese in
almost all the supermarkets across Mauritius.
This is an example of what we call a very simplified back-of-envelope difference-indifferences, in which the CCM assumed that, had it not intervened, there would
have been no entry, and price would have continued to rise at the same rate as it
had prior to the intervention. Clearly, such simple assumptions are really only
guesses and open to question. On the other hand, they render the required analysis
much less data and time-demanding. Other authorities quite often employ simple
before-after comparisons, for example the OFT in its ex-post impact evaluation of
the NAPP abuse case (OFT, 2011f).
7.3
Case 3: Pirelli/BICC merger (event study)
The Pirelli/BICC merger study was commissioned by the European Commission
(EC) and undertaken by LEAR Consulting (Buccirossi et al, 2006). It used, as an
example, the acquisition by Pirelli of six manufacturing plants in Italy and the UK
in the power cables industry. The merger had originally been investigated on the
basis of fears of collective dominance (coordinated effects) in two specific product
90
markets (in which Alcatel was the main rival) and single dominance (unilateral
effects) in another.
The data employed were taken from the Datastream database on the stock prices of
the rivals and customers of the merging parties at three sub-events: when the
merger was first proposed, then at EC’s announcement that it was going to instigate
a Phase 2 investigation, and finally at the clearance decision. On the basis of their
results, LEAR concluded that the merger was pro-competitive, that there was a
price reduction as a result of the merger, and that EC’s clearance decision was
correct.
In many ways, this particular study is a classic example of an event study. LEAR
itself concluded (2006, p.102) that ‚Overall this event study has been a successful
one, because it has provided some clear results on the effect of the merger. If
compared to many of the results generally observed in the literature, the effects that
we have estimated are particularly significant.‛ This is certainly true. Indeed, this
particular industry should provide fertile ground for the use of an event study
since many of the relevant firms are large and quoted on stock exchanges – the
latter being a necessary condition for an event study. Having said this, even in such
a large scale important industry such as this, only 5 of the 11 rivals were publicly
quoted and only 17 of the 29 customers. So at the least this raising concerns about
selection bias. Moreover, many of the 22 quoted sample firms were multinational
and diversified, raising doubts whether their stock valuations would be sensitive to
a merger between two of their rivals in just two countries in only one of their lines
of business.
In fact, inspection of the detailed results of this event study reveals that the merger
had no impact on rivals (the expectation is that a coordinated effects merger would
raise the rivals’ profitability) and a mixed impact on customers (the expectation is
that an anti-competitive merger would lead the financial market to reduce its
assessment of customers’ profitability). Indeed, more customers than not appear to
have benefited according to the stock market, and to cite extreme examples,
Energia’s stock increased by 16 per cent, Verbund by 9 per cent and National Grid
by 6 per cent at the time of the merger announcement. However, on reflection, these
magnitudes appear to be implausibly high – by how much would the price of one
input in one market have to fall for the profitability of the using firm to rise by as
much as 16 per cent? Moreover, as just noted, there was an absence of significant
impacts on rivals – while it is indeed true that this result is consistent with the
merger having no adverse competitive impact, it is also consistent with a more
cynical interpretation that the merger (whatever its competitive impact) would
have no noticeable effect on the future profitability of such large multinational
diversified firms. If the latter interpretation is correct, this suggests that the event
study may often be impotent in even the most superficially promising cases.
91
7.4
Case 4: Antitrust fines in South African bread and flour cartels
(event study)
Similar to the previous case, this case also employs an event study but applied to
estimate the impact of fines on the stock market valuations of infringing firms
involved in bread and flour cartels in South Africa (Darj et al., 2011). It has been
selected deliberately as a second example of evaluation from a relatively young
competition authority outside of Europe.55 It is also far less technical, and was
presumably much less time-consuming than the previous case.
Interestingly, the authors of the study comment: ‚In South Africa, there are not
many listed companies that have been found guilty of contravening the Act and as
such there are only a limited number of companies that we can focus on (p. 6)‛.
However in this case three key firms involved in the cartels are quoted on the
Johannesburg Stock Exchange, and the authors were able to conduct a
straightforward but competent event study analysis. Contrary to event study
merger applications, in which the focus is on rival and perhaps customer firms, the
objective here was much simpler – to identify the impact of a fine on just the
profitability of the firm itself. The authors’ chosen event dates were the day on
which a fine was imposed and then the day of any subsequent settlement with the
Commission. The resulting estimates of impact on future profitability were
generally plausible. On average, the reduction in company value over the event
window was about 7.5 per cent - fairly typical of studies such as this.
This case is a good example of how an event study can be used successfully in a
straight forward to quantify the effects of intervention on the firm concerned – as is
possible with fines. Importantly, the impact of a fine may exceed the simple cost of
the fine itself because of other potential indirect effects on the firm’s future
profitability. In principle, these might include a deterrent effect – the firm will be
less likely to be involved in future cartels – and the possibility that its customers
might be more cost-conscious when dealing with the firm in future. There is no real
complication regarding the counterfactual which is fairly obvious in the case of
fines.
7.5
Case 5: Volvo-Scandia (simulation)
The Volvo-Scandia case is selected as an example of an academic merger simulation
– in fact, a full-fledged technically quite advanced simulation of a proposed merger
between Volvo and Scandia in the European truck (lorry) market. The authors,
Ivaldi and Verboven, were involved in the original European Commission
investigation of the case, but here we cite their account as subsequently described
in their article in an academic journal (Ivaldi and Verboven, 2005). That article
55
Other better known cartel cases are already referenced in section 6.
92
emphasises the methodology more than the results of the evaluation per se, and it
has since become a widely cited standard reference in Industrial Organisation texts
used to illustrate state of the art simulation techniques.
At the heart of their methodology is the econometric estimation of the demand
system of equations for trucks. This uses panel data for 16 different Member States
over two years. Prices are the list prices of a base model and sales are total sales for
the model range. The econometric model used is nested logit – a special case of the
random utility function – and it is necessary to include variables reflecting the
different characteristics of different models of trucks. However, and this is a
potential weakness of their estimation, only one truly technical characteristic was
employed – the truck’s horsepower. In practice, of course, technical specification
(and therefore consumers’ willingness to pay) is likely to depend on many other
technical features of a particular truck. Perhaps such data were unavailable.
Estimation of the demand system provided the authors with estimates of the
relevant price elasticities.
The effects of the merger were then simulated by introducing their chosen noncooperative oligopoly model (i.e. unilateral effects) and analytically solving for (i)
the equilibrium prices assuming first no merger (i.e. before) and then (ii) with the
merger (i.e. after). In this case the merger was actually prohibited so the difference
between the before and after price equilibria generates an estimate of the price rise
avoided by the EC’s prohibition. It appears, on the basis of this simulation, that the
EC made broadly the correct decision.
This case illustrates well many of the standard strengths and weaknesses of merger
simulation. It forces the analyst to specify quite explicitly what is the chosen
counterfactual, but it is also possible to simulate alternative counterfactuals
(oligopoly games). In itself, the rigour of the simulation model also requires the
analyst to form a detailed understanding of the nature of competition and demand
in the market concerned. On the other hand, results can be very sensitive to
alternative assumptions, and data demands can be prohibitive – often requiring
approximations (e.g. here the paucity of measures of product characteristics).
Finally, when conducted at the level of technical complexity employed here,
simulation can be time- and resource-consuming and require highly skilled
econometricians.
7.6
Case 6: UK merger review (back-of-envelope simulation)
This final case is chosen as a contrast to the previous one in that the simulation was
deliberately much more simplistic but also far less time consuming. It was
conducted in a matter of days, rather than months or years.
93
The chosen study is a broad-based evaluation of eight different mergers, conducted
by the consultants Deloitte’s for a consortium of UK authorities (2007).56 Their
purpose was to conduct a review of merger decisions under the relatively new
Enterprise Act of 2002, in particular, reviewing the decisions and the quality of
decision making on which they were based, in the light of subsequent
developments in the market. The assessment was based on two approaches. The
first was a qualitative survey using interviews with market participants,
supplemented by questionnaires and publicly available data. The second was to
conduct ex-ante simulation on as many of the cases as possible, simulating what the
likely consequences of the mergers would be, but using only information that was
available to the authorities at the times of their decisions. The simulations, which
were undertaken by the present author, were confined to back-of-envelope simple
methods which could be effected quickly and with minimal data requirements.
In the event, given data limitations, simulation was possible for only four of the
eight cases. In each of these, the product was effectively homogenous and capacity
constraints were typically an issue. For this reason, the model used was a capacityconstrained Cournot model. Given the simplicity of the model and the limited
nature of the available data, the purpose of the simulation was not to provide
precise quantified estimates of by how much each of the mergers would have
raised price, but more to suggest broadly the sort of magnitudes which might have
been involved. As it turned out, these simulations were supportive of the
authorities’ decision, in that they suggested that there would have been very high
increases in the case where the merger was prohibited, but only very moderate for
the other three, all of which were cleared. In one of those three cases however, the
market conditions suggested that, perhaps, the merger might have coordinated
effects, and these could have led to much higher price increases. In that case, the
Competition Commission judged that coordinated effects were, in fact, unlikely.
Here, the simulation confirmed that the clearance decision was correct, but
conditional on the assumption that coordinated effects would not occur. Whether
or not that assumption could, in principle, be evaluated by an ex-post evaluation,
but that was not the purpose of this particular project.
This study illustrates quite well what can, and what can not, be achieved by backof-envelope simulation. Its strength is in speed and simplicity, and thus the
capability of application to a number of different cases in a fairly short period of
research time. Its weakness is that it can often only be applied to simple markets
(here, in which competition could be described by simple Cournot models, albeit
capacity constrained), or in which simple diversion ratios can be used to model
product differentiation. Moreover, a danger with simulation models is the spurious
sense of precision and accuracy it might encourage. In this particular project, the
authors correctly stressed that such simulations should be viewed only as devices
The consortium included the Competition Commission, the OFT and the Department of
Business, Enterprise and Regulatory Reform.
56
94
for showing how different assumptions about the market and the nature of
competition might translate into different evaluations of the likely impact of
different decisions. In other words, their role is to provide only one of a number of
different aids to the decision-making.
The other noteworthy feature of the study was the combination of the quantitative
simulations with the qualitative survey. The latter provides a number of additional
insights which could not have been identified from a quantitative analysis alone –
(i) in three cases there was significant entry which had not been anticipated by the
CC; (ii) apparent inconsistency across cases in the threshold number of firms in
local markets which the CAs used to action interventions, (iii) a question mark on
how best to handle self-supply when defining vertically related markets.
95
8
Some Important Under-developed Issues
Throughout the report, we have flagged where there are gaps, uncertainties and
unresolved issues in the previous literatures and practices. In this penultimate
section, we discuss three of the most important in greater depth. These reflect the
author’s own views on the areas in which further work is particularly required.
8.1
Selection bias and deterrence
Inevitably, evaluation studies focus on documented cases in the public domain, and
amongst these, usually the ones where an intervention has actually occurred or
been seriously contemplated. As noted frequently in the literature, this raises a
variety of doubts about whether such a sample can provide an unbiased estimate of
the benefits of competition policy. It also leaves open the problematic issue of how
to treat the deterrent effect. This section draws together various strands in a fairly
disparate existing literature on selection bias and deterrence into a coherent
framework which highlights the most pressing questions for future research.
8.1.1 Some potential sources of selection bias
As stressed throughout this report, one source of bias comes from the fact that
different evaluation methodologies are less practicable for some types of markets
and interventions (e.g. event studies for markets populated by unquoted or
conglomerate firms). In addition, previous literature contains numerous other
instances of why evaluation is susceptible to selection bias problems; the following
examples illustrate some of the issues.
In the empirical literature on cartels (e.g. duration and overcharge) it is widely
understood that the samples analysed may be intrinsically biased because they are
drawn exclusively from detected investigated cases, which may not be
representative of the unknown population of undetected cases.
When the rigour of merger policy is evaluated using a sample of unchallenged
mergers, Carlton (2009) points to an easily overlooked bias. He poses the question:
‘suppose we observe that the mean price increase in a sample of unchallenged
mergers is negative, can we deduce that the CA is sufficiently (or even over-)
strict?’ The answer is no because, even with a lax CA (inclined to Type I errors),
such a sample will include ‘good’ mergers alongside any incorrectly permitted
‘bad’ (price increasing) mergers. He suggests that any such evaluation should more
properly compare outcomes with the CA’s predictions at the time of its decisions to
estimate the systemic bias in enforcement.
96
It is widely acknowledged that the beneficial deterrent effects of competition
enforcement are likely to be considerable, probably far outweighing the measurable
benefits of the actual caseloads of CAs. It follows that any evaluation of the benefits
of policy based only on investigated cases may be a serious underestimate,
probably by an order of magnitude; however, we know remarkably little about the
magnitudes of this global underestimate.
The remainder of this section introduces a classification scheme designed to
structure the various dimensions of potential selection bias and highlight directions
for future research.
8.1.2 How much of the iceberg lies below the waterline?
Figure 8.1 suggests a stylised classification scheme to describe the full distribution
of all potential competition cases in the population.57 Some of these cases are
deterred and never occur; amongst the undeterred cases, some will be detected but
some not; and then, within the detected set, some are investigated and some are
not.58
This classification is used to illustrate some of the selection problems which would
need to be resolved if one is to extrapolate from what we know (the investigated
cases) to what we do not (the deterred, undetected and un-investigated parts of the
population). We proceed in two steps, considering first the relative sizes
(frequencies of cases) of the classes, and then the potential heterogeneity between
the classes (measured by, say, mean expected harm), which reflects any potential
selection bias.
This notion of a well-defined population of potential cases is not unproblematic, given that it is
to include all deterred anti-competitive practices. Applying such a classification, analogously, to
the law criminalising murder would require one to quantify the number of murders that would
be committed were the practice not illegal.
57
In reality the picture is even more complex. For example investigated cases can be broken
down into cases settled by the parties and cases that reach the CA’s final decision. Within this
latter group there are cases where the CA intervenes and ones without intervention. Impact
evaluations are typically based in this latter sub-sample of cases. This means selection issues
arise on at least two extra levels.
58
97
Figure 8.1 A general classification of potential competition cases
Deterred
ω
Undeterred
(1-ω)
Undetected
Detected
(1-φ)
φ
Uninvestigated
(1-σ)
Investigated
σ
Source: Davies and Ormosi (2010)
Relative frequencies
Denoting the conditional probabilities by: deterrence rate (ω), detection rate (φ),
and investigation rate (σ), it follows that the sample of investigated cases:

Property 1: represents only a (perhaps very) small proportion, (1ω)*(φ)*(σ), of the population of all potentially relevant cases.

Property 2: fails to capture any beneficial deterrent effect.

Property 3: fails to capture the ‘missed opportunities’ represented by
harmful cases that are either wrongly un-investigated or undetected.59
The first two are trivial, but the third is often overlooked in evaluation studies.
A back-of-envelope quantification
It remains for future work to establish how rigorously these three properties might
be quantified, but to illustrate how information already in the public domain might
be employed, we draw on a rare qualitative study by Deloitte (2007), commissioned
by the OFT.60 This involved interviews/telephone surveys of lawyers, economists
and companies. The key findings (2007, pp. 7-12) on deterrence are shown in Table
8.1. From the survey of legal advisers, they suggest that, for each merger blocked or
modified by the CA, there were at least another five proposed mergers that were
abandoned or modified on competition grounds. Their ‘multiplier’ was slightly
smaller for potential abuse of dominance cases, but higher for commercial
We abstract for the moment from possible offsetting effects, e.g. deterrence of welfareenhancing mergers, and incorrect Type II intervention decisions.
59
The Dutch competition authority (NMa) also conducted a survey (2005) to estimate the scope
of merger deterrence. See also OFT (2011c) for a recent updating of Deloitte’s (2007) study.
60
98
agreements (Article 101). According to their survey of the companies themselves,
the reported multipliers were all considerably higher.
Table 8.1
Deterrence multipliers
Legal survey
Company survey
Mergers
5:1
–
Cartels
5:1
16:1
Commercial agreements
7:1
29:1
Abuses
4:1
10:1
Source: derived from Deloitte (2007)
Turning to undetected cases, Deloitte report that the number of 'under the radar'
(i.e. undetected by the OFT) mergers was at least as high as the number which are
blocked or modified following intervention by the UK competition authorities.61
These estimates should be interpreted with considerable caution (see the
qualifications stressed in the report itself), but taken at face value, and arbitrarily
assuming a value of 0.5 for σ the investigation rate (in principle, this could be
computed from the CA’s own records), we can back out estimates of the
probabilities as in Table 8.2, and then the population frequencies as in Table 8.3.
Table 8.2
Deterrence and detection probabilities
ω62
φ
Cartels
0.56
0.17
Mergers
0.56
0.5
63
Source: Author’s calculations using the data from Table 8.1.
The three above properties can then be quantified as: (i) the investigated sample is
only about 10 per cent of the full population of potential mergers and less than 4
Strictly speaking the survey reports that the number of undetected problematic mergers was at
least as high as the number of investigated ones, in which case the total detection rate may be
much lower than 50%.
61
This uses the Deloitte finding of 5 deterred cases for each investigated case, ω = 5(1- ω)φσ,
from which ω can be calculated using the estimations for φ, and the arbitrarily chosen 0.5 for σ.
62
63
Based on Ormosi (2011) discussed below.
99
per cent of potential cartels,64 (ii) there are five (fifteen) times as many deterred as
investigated merger (cartels). On the other hand, (iii) there are three (ten) times as
many ‘missed opportunities’ (undetected or un-investigated) as investigated
mergers (cartels) cases.
Table 8.3
Calculated frequencies for categories
Cartels
Mergers
Deterred
0.556
0.556
Undetected
0.368
0.222
Un-investigated
0.0377
0.111
Investigated
0.0377
0.111
Source: Author’s calculations using the data from Table 8.1.
Needless to say, these estimates are presented for merely illustrative purposes –
they show the implications of the Deloitte study in particular, but we reserve
judgement on whether or not they might be credible.
8.1.3 Heterogeneity between case classes (selection bias)
It should also be stressed that the above calculations relate only to the frequencies of
each class – they do not quantify the relative amounts of deterred harm or missed
opportunities. This would only be true if the expected harm of cases in all
categories were identical. However, the possibility of selection bias raises suspicion
that expected harm will differ systematically between the classes of case in Figure
1.65
First, it is important to note that the distinction between categories is not clear cut,
and that the frequencies and make-up of the classes are endogenous to the policy
decisions of the CA. Consider mergers as an example. In jurisdictions where there
is a compulsory pre-merger notification regime (most of the world) a regulatory
threshold demarcates the cases that do not have to be notified. Above the threshold
there are three types of cases: (1) those where there is only a trivial preliminary
screening, (2) phase 1 cases; (3) phase 2 cases. Although all cases above the
Even if we assume that all known cases are investigated (i.e. σ = 1) these ratios will still only be
22% and 10% respectively.
64
The OFT (2010c) p.22. speculates about applying a multiplier to account for the deterrent effect
of its enforcement activity, where the value of the multiplier is derived from the Deloitte survey.
This method implicitly assumes that the distribution of case types in the investigated and
deterred classes are similar.
65
100
threshold theoretically have to be investigated (i.e. the CA has no discretion), it is
arguable whether a simplistic screening of the merger (or even a phase I review, as
discussed below) should qualify as an investigation. So the question for mergers is:
where to draw the line below which we consider cases as un-investigated.66
The possibility that CA discretion may have an important distortional impact on
evaluation is not confined to just mergers, and the choices made by the CA are an
integral part of its policy and should therefore also form part of any evaluation. The
key idea here is that a CA is confronted with a set of potential cases where it could
assemble sufficient information to undertake a full investigation (and subsequently
possibly intervene) but, in the event, it chooses not to pursue them all, for example
because there is a low success rate if the case is appealed.67
This possibility cannot be excluded as one possible explanation for the previously
highlighted scarcity of evaluations of abuse of dominance cases – perhaps CAs
choose to intervene less frequently in such cases. Similarly for cartels, Chang and
Harrington (2010) argue that the CA’s decision to investigate a case is a matter of
CA choice, and success is negatively correlated with the CA’s workload.
Of course, given finite resources, coupled with a need to substantiate its impact, it is
rational for any CA to pursue the ‘easy options’; i.e. easier cases at the expense of
more difficult cases (for which the probability of ‘success’ is lower or where there is
greater uncertainty). This may have serious implications for selection bias – both for
policy in general and in specific parts (e.g. abuse of dominance). We believe that
this issue merits further research.
A related danger is highlighted by Neven and Zengler (2008, p.477), who suggest
that the evaluation programme itself may introduce an additional motive for
distortional discretion in CA conduct: ‚Faced with simplistic assessment,
authorities may be tempted to be overly interventionist, to spend too many
resources and to ignore relevant information‛. This returns us to the question of
what is the purpose of evaluation, and who undertakes it. If evaluation is driven by
external accountability (to verify whether the CA delivers its objectives) and
especially if undertaken by the CA itself, the CA is prone to fall into the trap
identified by Chang and Harrington (2010), that it will not seek to maximise
deterrence, but focus on something that is observable/measurable (e.g. the
proportion of Article 102 cases that are won, or the number of cartels detected). This
could easily mean that enhanced deterrence is not in the interest of the CA if that
were to reduce its caseload – and consequently the number of cases won. Although
this might seem a questionable assumption, there is some intuition to support it:
In non-mandatory pre-merger notification regimes (such as the UK) the situation is different as
the CA has more discretion whether to investigate mergers.
66
Neven (2006) reports a 98% success rate for Abuse of dominance cases (as opposed to a 75%
success rate for Article 101 and 58% for merger cases).
67
101
deterrence is difficult to measure and therefore include in any performance
measure of the CA. If the CA's budget is based on previous years' performance,
which excludes deterrence, then the assumption becomes more plausible.
8.1.4 Existing academic literature on detection and deterrence
The task of calibrating the three parameters and quantifying likely magnitudes of
associated selection biases is formidable. In our opinion the investigation rate is
potentially the easiest to estimate, and could be acquired from the CA’s own
records. Detection and especially deterrence are more problematic but there have
been attempts to estimate the probability of both of these categories. These are
summarised in Table 8.4.
The detection rate is not directly observable of course, but a body of emerging
research offers some promise that indirect estimation may be possible using
relatively atheoretical statistical methods. This research also has implications for the
rate of deterrence, but may involve additional theoretical modelling of the creation
of mergers, cartels and other business practices. More work is clearly needed – for
example, on whether observed CA activity and latent deterrence are
complementary or substitutes.68 Similarly, little work has been done on determining
the key drivers of antitrust deterrence. As described earlier, the results from Broek,
Kemp et al. (2012) suggest that deterrence may be driven by reputational factors as
well as the legal penalty per se. More generally, there may be fruitful avenues of
research drawing on the wider legal deterrence literature. For instance, the critique
by Donohue and Wolfers (2006) - of the common mistakes made in the statistical
analysis of the deterrent effect of the death penalty - might be helpful.
Finally, it should be acknowledged that over-stringent policy can sometimes deter
welfare enhancing practices or proposals. This would include mergers which might
lead to strong efficiency effects; vertical practices (perhaps RPM) where the
beneficial efficiency gains outweigh any anti-competitive foreclosure effect; or even
cases where firms may refrain from fierce price competition because they are
deterred by predatory pricing policy. This is rarely even discussed in CA
evaluations, although admittedly quantification would be difficult. An interesting
example is given by Eckbo (1992), who finds no evidence of Canadian mergers
having anticompetitive effects. If so, it follows that any deterred merger must be
either a welfare loss, or at least no gain.
This might be approached statistically by comparative analysis of high and low deterrence
authorities.
68
102
Table 8.4
Previous attempts
deterrence rates
to
estimate
investigation,
detection
and
Observed
Probabilities of interest
Investigation rate
Source of data
CA’s records
Literature examples
–
Unobserved
Detection rate
Atheoretical empirical
methods
Bryant and Eckard
(1991)
Ormosi (2010)
Miller (2009)
Harrington et al.
(2009)
Chang et al. (2010)
OFT (2007)
Beckstein and LandisGabel (1982)
Barros et al. (2010)
Block et al. (1981)
Harrington et al.
(2009)
Cheng et al. (2010)
NMa (2005)
Theory-based empirical
methods
Surveys
Unobserved
Deterrence rate
CA’s records
Theory-based empirical
methods
Surveys
Source: Author’s compilation
8.2
The need for longer term studies
In general it is difficult to assess the long-run effect of any public policy, given the
exponential rise of possible compounding effects with time, which makes it difficult
to distinguish effects that were caused by the intervention from effects triggered by
exogenous factors. One potential way of doing this is through case studies
regarding the evolution of markets following regulatory intervention.69 This could
highlight concerns about the time dimension which applies to any one-off
evaluation (no matter what the methodology is) – that it runs the risk of closing the
story prematurely. The wider IO literature (both theoretical and empirical) suggests
various possibilities for how a specific event might trigger a sequence or chain of
subsequent events – each of which might be evaluated independently, but which
are in reality clearly path-dependent. For example, the literature on endogenous
mergers alerts us to the possibility that, if merger A is cleared, this makes a
subsequent merger B more or less likely. Similarly, in failing firm merger cases, the
consequences of intervention may include subsequent alternative merger proposals
Another way would be to examine how competition policy shaped firms’ long-run decisions
that are formed immediately following the policy intervention. This way the scope of possible
compounding effects is reduced to minimum and we get some sort of idea about longer-run
impacts. To define long-run decisions for example Symeonidis (2002) refers to those decisions
that determine the set of conditions that firms must take as given when making short-run
choices. One example would be firms investing in long-run R&D projects following competition
intervention.
69
103
by other parties as happened in the case of Airtours.70 Airtours had to change its
brand name (My Travel group) following the blocking of its takeover attempt on
First Choice. Eventually My Travel was acquired by Thomas Cook Travel.
There is case study evidence which suggests that sometimes when some practice is
prohibited, it is replaced by others. Clarke et al. (1998) cite examples from the UK
where firms responded to the prohibition of one form of vertical restraint by
introducing an alternative form, or where a prohibited restraint was replaced by
full-fledged integration. In other cases, such as following intervention in
exclusionary abuse of dominance the market may trigger market entry in the
longer-run. For example following the US intervention in the bundling of Microsoft
Internet Explorer web-browser and the Windows operating system the market of
web-browsers now accommodates three larger firms (Internet Explorer, Firefox,
and Google Chrome) and a fringe with a number of other browsers.
It has long been recognised that horizontal mergers may sometimes be an
alternative to cartelisation. Symeonidis (2002) shows that cartel legislation in the
UK in the 1950s provoked a subsequent merger wave through the 1960s. Similarly,
following the 2002 detection of a cartel, which included Mittal Steel and Arcelor
(the first and second-largest steel producers in the world), in 2006 the two firms
merged.71
Sidak and Teece (2009) provide an insightful discussion on why competition
analysis has been so one-sidedly fixated on static effects. They draw upon recent
developments in evolutionary economics, the behavioural theory of the firm, and
strategic management to propose a more dynamic and robust support for
competition economics. Although their discussion focuses mostly on enforcement
issues, much it has direct relevance for ex-post impact evaluation as well.
Finally, liberalisation and privatisation (and potentially the advocacy activities of
CAs that may trigger liberalisation) will also have long as well as short-term
impacts. Sector inquiries by the EC are prime examples of evaluation that looks
back to market interventions such as liberalisation and examines how the market
evolved in the medium and longer run.72 For example the EC report on leased
telecommunication lines found that the 1998 full liberalisation of the EU
telecommunications infrastructure and services brought about greater choice for
The Airtours/First Choice merger was blocked in 2000 by the EC although the decision was
overturned by the ECJ in 2002 – although the deal by then had been long dead.
70
Although Kumar, Marshall et al. (2011) claim that ceteris paribus, firms choose cartels over
mergers, suggesting that they perceive the payoffs to a cartel to be higher than the payoffs to the
merger of the same firms.
71
The EC has so far published sector inquiries in the following markets: pharmaceuticals,
financial services, energy, local loop, leased lines, roaming, and media (3G). For more
information see: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/sector_inquiries.html
72
104
users, lower prices and better quality of services across the EU.73 At the other
extreme, the inquiry into the European energy sector, found that years after the
liberalisation of the internal energy market, barriers to free competition remain.74
OECD Country Reviews also frequently provide a longer perspective analysis of
liberalisation and privatisation activities in the past.
To summarise, it matters what happens after the intervention, and ‘after’ should
sometimes be interpreted as long-term and not too narrowly. The importance of
looking at longer effects is unquestionable. As Werden (2008) pointed out citing
Easterbrook (1992): ‚An antitrust policy that reduced prices by 5% today at the
expense of reducing by 1% the annual rate at which innovation lowers the cost of
production would be a calamity. In the long run a continuous rate of change,
compounded, swamps static losses.‛ Some evaluation studies have acknowledged
this, albeit indirectly, by considering sequences of cases, for example Sabbatini
(2008) for Italian baby-milk; Pinske and Slade (2004) for a sequence of mergers in
UK beer and Nevo (2000) who includes various different mergers in his
simulations, but these are the exception rather than the rule.
8.3
The broader impact of competition policy
Most of the literature, and therefore discussion, in this report has focussed rather
specifically on the impact of enforcement on consumer welfare. However, we
should also be concerned with the wider impact on the economy as a whole and the
macro aggregates of growth, investment, employment as well as productivity and
innovation.
There are empirical studies which explore these areas, but in general the literature
is thin and of variable quality. This section provides a brief overview,
distinguishing between two strands of literature: works that examine the impact of
competition on productivity, growth, etc, and research that attempts to measure the
impact of competition enforcement on the same factors.
8.3.1 The effects of competition
There are grounds for expecting that competition can help fuel economic growth
through at least three different channels: (i) exerting pressure on firm management
to reduce inefficiencies (Meyer and Vickers (1997), Schmidt (1997); McKinsey
http://ec.europa.eu/competition/sectors/telecommunications/archive/inquiries/leased_lines/
index.html
73
Inquiry pursuant to Article 17 of Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 into the European gas and
electricity sectors.
74
105
Global Institute (2010b, p.28)); (ii) by fostering innovation,75, 76 and (iii) by guiding a
better allocation of resources to more efficient firms (Arnold et al.,2008). It can also
help create a more favourable macroeconomic environment in various other ways,
such as through reducing inflation rates,77 or improving international
competitiveness.78
The main challenge in this literature is to find an adequate measure of
competition.79 Simple measures such as market concentration do not always
provide a reliable stand-in for competition.80 Price-cost margins (PCM) have been a
popular measure although not fully supported by economic theory.81 Boone (2008)
offers an alternative to PCM; a measure that has a more robust theoretical backing
and has the same data requirements as for PCM. One frequently used way of
measuring competition follows the seminal paper by Nickell (1996), who estimates
the impact of competition on firm performance. To proxy for competition, Nickell
used a mix of measures including market share, concentration, import penetration,
a survey-based measure of competition, and a measure of average rents.82 Another
way of measuring product market competition is given by Przybyla and Roma
(2005) who use a different mix of measures, which includes mark-up measured as
the inverse of the labour income share in the economy, profit margin as the ratio of
operating surplus to output, profit rate as net unadjusted operating surplus/capital
stock, a World Economic Forum (2002) index number, the level of regulation, and
market openness. Finally, Haffner et al. (2000) use simple measures such as
similarities and convergence over time of price structures, differences in price levels
and estimates of the levels and trends of profit margins. The rationale behind this is
the intuition that if competition was intensive then cross-border competitive
pressure would result in prices converging at a European level. Another frequently
used ‘proxy’ for competition is trade liberalisation, which is used in time-series or
Gilbert (2008) surveys economic theory and empirical studies on the relation between market
structure innovation.
75
In a survey of more than 26,000 manufacturing establishments across 71 countries Dutz et al.
(2011) found empirical evidence that innovation drives employment growth and that the
underlying innovations are fostered by a pro-competitive business environment. .
76
77
Przybyla and Roma (2005).
78
Mitschke (2008).
Aghion and Griffith (2005) give a detailed overview of the development of econometric
techniques aimed at measuring competition, productivity, and innovation.
79
80
See for example Boone (2001).
81
See Boone (2008) for a brief discussion on this matter.
Nickell finds that competition is associated with higher rates of total factor productivity
growth.
82
106
longitudinal structural analyses. Most of these studies find robust evidence for the
positive effect of competition on firm performance, growth and productivity.83
8.3.2 The effects of competition enforcement
One example of a study of this type is the OFT (2011b) who examine the impact of
competition interventions on various elements of economic growth, such as natural
resources, capital, innovation, and management. A key challenge in this line of
literature is to find appropriate measures of competition enforcement or
competition policy. 84 Buccirossi et al. (2009a) warn of this and claim that the lack of
evidence of a positive effect of competition policy in some of the studies is a result
of inadequate measures. In this respect, competition policy indices, such as the ones
in World Economic Forum (2002), Buccirossi et al. (2009a), and Hüschelrath and
Leheyda (2010) may be better suited to capture those characteristics that are likely
to have an impact on the effectiveness of policy. The composition of a competition
policy index typically relies on institutional and enforcement characteristics such as
the degree of formal independence of the CA, the separation of adjudicatory and
prosecutor functions within the CA, the scope of investigative powers of the CA,
the level of enforcement (size of sanctions, size of budgets and resources, etc)., and
the seriousness of sanctions that the CA can impose.85 The related econometric
problems are familiar in any international comparisons based on production
functions or related concepts, e.g. identification, simultaneity and the requirement
that the underlying functional forms are stable across countries.86
Competition policy, when interpreted more widely than just the enforcement of
competition laws, has also contributed to economic growth. This includes
government policies on facilitating market entry, for example by liberalising or
privatising markets. European-wide market liberalisation for example has led to
greater competition and consequently reduced prices across Europe.87 More
specifically there is evidence that market liberalisation has contributed to
See OECD (2011). For a review of studies on non OECD member countries see: Tussie and
Aggio (2006) and Parikh and Stirbu (2004).
83
Some of these aggregate studies are discussed and well summarised by Bergman (2008), who
provides some of the key references.
84
Which reflects the understanding that the effectiveness of competition law enforcement largely
depends on the strength of legal systems, the quality of the judiciary system, and other indicators
of legal origin (La Porta, de Silanes et al. (2008)).
85
One area where more work would be welcome is a comparison of the impact of competition
enforcement on socio-economic factors depending on whether the CA’s decisions are rooted in
static or dynamic economic analyses. Following the arguments from Sidak and Teece (2008) one
would expect that the latter should show a more positive impact.
86
87
McKinsey Global Institute (2010a)
107
innovation and productivity, for example in the UK,88 India,89 or China.90 Reducing
barriers to entry and trade, and eliminating price controls also increases
employment rate through increased demand in markets.91
The impact of competition policy in the geographically broader sense is a yet
unexplored area, where more work is long overdue. Competition policy impacts
conducts that are turning increasingly global in their scope. Therefore the
enforcement of competition law and the design of competition policy in one
country will inevitably have an effect on other economies, although effects of
competition policy in one country may be difficult to disentangle from the effects of
competition policy from another country. The challenges of measuring this type of
impact are similar to some of the already discussed issues.
88
Aghion, Blundell et al. (2009).
89
Sivadasan (2009)
90
Zheng and Ward (2011)
91
Griffith, Harrison et al. (2006)
108
9
Conclusions
By way of a conclusion, I turn to three questions on which I have been asked to
advise as part of my research brief: (i) why should a CA carry out evaluations of its
own work? (ii) how should it do it? (iii) what are the challenges that CAs face in the
field? In each case, my answers necessarily express personal opinions, and while
they are based on a fairly extensive experience in the field, they are the inevitably
opinions of someone who is obviously committed to the evaluation project.
9.1
Why should CAs evaluate their own work?
As explained in the opening section of this report, evaluation has been carried out
for a variety of reasons, some of which are clearly in the self-interest of Competition
Authorities. Here, I will highlight three.
First, on the assumption that competitive markets are an essential ingredient of an
efficient, innovate and flexible economy, there is clearly a role for active
competition law and policy. In turn, given that governments face a multitude of
potential demands on the public purse, it is important that the enforcement of
competition policy (broadly defined) should attract an appropriate share of the
state’s budget. The evidence from the competition authorities who have been most
prominent to date in evaluating competition policy (the UK, US and EC), is that the
enforcement of competition law does indeed provide exceptional ‘value for money.’
For example, the OFT currently estimates that every £1 it spends yields
approximately £10 of benefits to consumers. While one can always argue about and
perhaps question the details involved in deriving such a figure, the sheer
magnitude speaks for itself – especially when it is remembered that conservative
assumptions are used throughout and, crucially, that no allowance has been made
for the probably substantial additional benefits deriving from deterrence.
In my opinion, it is important that the value of competition policy is appreciated
beyond the walls of the competition authorities, and that any competition authority
should be able to confidently and justifiably claim that the benefits deriving from
its activities far exceed the costs involved.
Second, at a more micro level, regular and fairly comprehensive evaluation, should
provide an essential ingredient in internal resource allocation decisions within the
authority. When allocating its budget between its different activities (merger
control, detection of cartels, monitoring of dominant firms), it is important to know
what is the likely marginal product of spending an additional euro in each area.
More generally, allocational decisions – say between detection and deterrence should be informed by some notion of the potential pay-offs.
109
Third, in any busy competition authority, there is an inherent danger that once a
decision or intervention has been made, it is consigned to a file which is then never
again opened. Ex-post evaluation provides probably the best means for ensuring
that the authority becomes aware of ‘what happens next’ in a market. Of particular
importance is the question of how markets react to, and perform, after
interventions. Moreover, evaluation provides a valuable check of whether the
assumptions, analysis and decision making taken at the time of the decision
vindicated by what happens in subsequent years.
However, there are some caveats, two of which deserve special emphasis. The first
is that we should not become slavishly attached to the precise estimates derived in
any evaluation. By its nature, evaluation will always be an imprecise subject, based
inevitably on assumptions which are typically approximate and sometimes
(regarding the counterfactual) never verifiable on a purely empirical basis.
Evaluation is there to guide rather than dictate. For this reason, it may always be
prudent to avoid giving a spurious impression of precision by presenting estimates
of impact in the form of a range rather than a precise single figure.
Second, and relatedly, there is an inherent danger that over-reliance on impact
estimates can distort allocational decisions within an authority. Faced with a
corporate objective of maximising the benefits to cost ratio, the danger is that
certain activities may go relatively neglected because their impact is more difficult
to measure. This is most obviously true for policies designed to enhance deterrence
– almost by definition, an anti-competitive act which is deterred will not show up
in any output measure. But, beyond this, certain policy areas are more difficult to
evaluate than others, and there is a danger that these may tend to be neglected if
the CA attaches over-importance to being able to measure impacts. This is certainly
true for advocacy and education, and perhaps also Article 102 cases. Hopefully this
position may be at least partly redressed if the evaluation of advocacy begins to
attract more attention in the future.
9.2 How should CAs conduct evaluation?
There have been two broad themes running through this report – deriving global
estimates of the aggregate impact of an authority’s activity, and then more
specifically the techniques which can be used to evaluate individual cases. It is my
view that the competition authority should do both – regularly (perhaps annually)
evaluating its overall impact and also devoting some resources to in-depth ex-post
evaluations of at least some specific cases. This is very much the model currently
used by the OFT.
There are a number of issues and decisions which would need to be resolved in
deriving aggregate impact evaluations – which rules of thumb to use for cartel
overcharge and duration etc., which areas of activity to evaluate? Here, the existing
110
practices of the OFT, DGCOMP, FTC and DoJ might be adopted, but, in the absence
of any internationally agreed best practice,92 this need not be essential.
Turning to the specific techniques of evaluation, Chapters 6 and 7 have shown that
there is no such thing as an ideal technique. Simulation, event studies, differencein-differences, before-after and more qualitative surveys all have strengths and
weaknesses, and each is more suited to some cases than others. In an ideal world, it
would be best practice to evaluate any given case using more than one different
technique to seek to establish robust findings. However, cost-, data- and timeconstraints will typically preclude this option. Perhaps the strongest message to
draw from this report is that sufficient time and attention should be devoted to
formulating an appropriate counterfactual (or alternative counterfactuals).
Sometimes, the nature of the counterfactual will dictate which evaluation technique
should be used.
A third broad recommendation is that the authority should adopt what might be
called a portfolio approach to its evaluation activities. Thus, there is much to be
said for employing a mix of ex-ante and ex-post evaluation - as do the other
authorities most frequently discussed in this report. Similarly, if only because of
cost-constraints, some of the evaluation should employ ‘back-of-envelope’
techniques, while others might be more thorough and technically advanced.
Finally, there are advantages in commissioning outsiders (consultancies and
academics) to do some, but not all, of the research. The obvious problem with inhouse evaluation is the suspicion that it will be seen as self-justifying and without
objectivity. On the other hand, it is important that the authority should develop its
own technical capabilities – not only is this good for the morale of the CA’s staff,
but also evaluation can generate important externalities (in developing human
capital and experience) for the CA’s core enforcement activities.
9.2
What are the challenges?
In Chapter 8, I have already identified three areas in which I think further work is
required in general. First, very little is known about the scale of undetected cases or
the strength of deterrence. This means that we have only a partial understanding of
the CA’s full impact or, for that matter, of the scale of its missed opportunities.
Second, most evaluation to date has focused on the short-term, with very few
analyses of the longer-term impact, taking into account how intervention will often
provoke responses by the firm in the markets concerned. Third, evaluation is often
confined to just price effects, with the impact on quality, choice, innovation,
productivity far less frequently assessed. This emphasis on price is understandable
– partly on practical grounds and partly because competition law itself emphasises
The author is aware that the OECD has recently embarked on its own evaluation research
programme, and the possibility of establishing international best practices will be considered
within this.
92
111
consumer surplus. However, potentially it seriously underestimates the true impact
of competition policy and this makes it sometimes difficult to respond to demands,
say from government, for quantifications of how much competition policy
contributes to growth and productivity.
More specifically, and confined to the activities that are currently assessed and the
techniques already used, the evaluation project is still very much ‘work in
progress’. Evaluation in some areas of policy is still under-developed, e.g.
advocacy, education and Article 102. Little is known, in a comparative sense about
the predictive performance of the different techniques. Here, the challenge is to
widen the scope of evaluation without unduly increasing the cost. As is true for
many policy areas, there is an important role for international cooperation and
diffusion of experience and skills.
112
10
References
Aghion, Philippe, Richard Blundell, Rachel Griffith, Peter Howitt and Susanne
Prantl. 2009. The Effects of Entry on Incumbent Innovation and Productivity Review of Economics and Statistics, 91, 1, 20-32.
Aghion, Philippe and Rachel Griffith. 2005. Competition and Growth: Reconciling
Theory and Evidence, The MIT Press.
Arisi, E. and F. M. Esposito. 2007. 'L’attivita di advocacy dell’Autorita Garante della
Concorrenza e del Mercato: un bilancio dei primi 15 anni (Advocacy by the Italian
Competition Authority: an overview over the first fifteen years)', unpublished paper
referenced in Sabbatini (2008).
Arnold, Jens, Giuseppe Nicoletti and Stefano Scarpetta. 2008. 'Regulation,
Allocative Efficiency and Productivity in OECD Countries: Industry and FirmLevel Evidence', OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 616.
Ashenfelter, Orley and Daniel Hosken. 2008. 'The effect of mergers on consumer
prices: evidence from five selected case studies', NBER Working Paper, Nº 13859.
Baker, Jonathan B. 2003. 'The Case for Antitrust Enforcement', Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 17, 4, 27-50.
Barros, Pedro P., Joseph A. Clougherty and Jo Seldeslachts. 2010. 'How to Measure
the Deterrence Effects of Merger Policy: Frequency or Composition?', International
Journal of the Economics of Business, 17, 1, 1-8
Beckstein, A., and H. Landis-Gabel. 1982. ‘Antitrust Compliance: Results of a
Survey of Legal Opinion’. Antitrust Law Journal, 52, 459-468.
Bergman, Mats A. 2008. 'Quis Custodiet Ipsos Custodes? or Measuring and
Evaluating the Effectiveness of Competition Enforcement', De Economist, 156, 4, 387409.
Becher, D. A. 2009. 'Bidder returns and merger anticipation: Evidence from banking
deregulation', Journal of Corporate Finance, 15, 85-98.
Beverley, L. 2008. 'Stock Market Event Studies and Competition Commission
Inquiries', CCP Working Paper No. 08-16
Bittlingmayer, G. and T.W. Hazlett. 2000. (DOS Kapital: Has antitrust action against
Microsoft created value in the computer industry?', Journal of Financial Economics,
55, 329-359.
113
Bizjak, J. M and J. L. Coles. 1995. 'The Effect of Private Antitrust Litigation on the
Stock-Market Valuation of the Firm', American Economic Review, 85, 3, 436-461.
Block, Michael Kent, Frederick Carl Nold and Joseph Gregory Sidak. 1981. 'The
deterrent effect of antitrust enforcement', Journal of Political Economy, 89, 3, 429-445.
Bolotova, Yuliya and John Connor. 2006. 'Cartel Overcharges: Survey and MetaAnalysis', International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 1109–1137.
Boone, Jan. 2001. 'Intensity of competition and the incentive to innovate',
International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19, 5, 705-726.
Boone, Jan. 2008. 'A new way to measure competition', The Economic Journal, 188,
1245-1261.
Borenstein, S. 1990. 'Airline Mergers, Airport Dominance, and Market Power',
American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 80, 400-404.
Bosch, Jean-Claude and E. Woodrow Eckard. 1991. 'The Profitability of Price Fixing:
Evidence from Stock Market Reaction to Federal Indictments', Review of Economics
and Statistics, 73, 309–317.
Broek, S. v. d., R. Kemp, et al. 2012. 'Reputational Penalties to Firms in Antitrust
Investigations', Journal of Competition Law & Economics, Forthcoming.
Bryant, Peter G. and E. Woodrow Eckard. 1991. 'Price Fixing: The Probability of
Getting Caught', The Review of Economics and Statistics, 73, 3, 531-536.
Buccirossi, Paolo, Lorenzo Ciari, Tomaso Duso, Sven-Olof Fridolfsson, Giancarlo
Spagnolo and Cristiana Vitale. 2006. 'Ex-post review of merger control decisions',
European Commission.
Buccirossi, Paolo, Lorenzo Ciari, Tomaso Duso, Sven-Olof Fridolfsson, Giancarlo
Spagnolo and Cristiana Vitale. 2008. 'A Short Overview of a Methodology for the
Ex-Post Review of Merger Control Decisions ', De Economist, 156, 4, 453-475.
Buccirossi, Paolo, Lorenzo Ciari, Tomaso Duso, Giancarlo Spagnolo and Cristiana
Vitale. 2009a. 'Competition Policy and Productivity Growth: An Empirical
Assessment', CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 7470.
Buccirossi, Paolo, Lorenzo Ciari, Tomaso Duso, Giancarlo Spagnolo and Cristiana
Vitale. 2009b. 'Measuring the Deterrence Properties of Competition Policy: the
Competition Policy Indexes', Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 7, 1, 165–204.
Budzinski, Oliver & Ruhmer, Isabel. 2010. Merger Simulation in Competition
Policy: A Survey, in: Journal of Competition Law & Economics, Vol. 6 (2), pp. 277-320.
114
Carletti, Elena, Philipp Hartmann and Steven Ongena. 2011. 'The Economic Impact
of Merger Control Legislation', CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP8447.
Carlton, Denis. 2009. 'Why we need to measure the effect of merger policy and how
to do it', Competition Policy International, 5, 1 (Spring), 76-90.
Chang, M. H. and J. E. Harrington. 2010. 'The Impact of a Corporate Leniency
Program on Antitrust Enforcement and Cartelization', available at:
http://www.econ.jhu.edu/pdf/papers/WP548.pdf.
Cichello, C. and D.J. Lamdin. 2006. 'Event Studies and the Analysis of Antitrust',
International Journal of Economics and Business, 13:2, 229-245.
Clarke, Roger, Stephen W. Davies and Nigel Driffield. 1998. Monopoly policy in the
UK: Assessing the evidence. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Colley, Liam and Marsden Philip. 2010, 'Use of the Counterfactual in Antitrust',
Competition Law Forum, at:
http://www.biicl.org/files/5106_the_use_of_the_counterfactual_in_antitrustv2.pdf
Competition Commission of Mauritius. 2011. Evaluation of CCM case
Connor, Robert A. , Roger D. Feldman and Bryan E. Dowd. 1998. 'The effects of
market concentration and horizontal mergers on hospital costs and prices',
International Journal of Economics and Business, 5, 2, 159-180.
Cooper, Z., S. Gibbons, et al. 2010. 'Does Hospital Competition Improve Efficiency?
An Analysis of the Recent Market-Based Reforms to the English NHS', CEP
Discussion Paper No 988.
Cox, A. J. and J. Portes. 1998. Mergers in Regulated Industries: the Uses and Abuses
of Event Studies, Journal of Regulatory Economics, 14, 3, 281-304.
Da Graca, T. 2006. 'Simultaneous Mergers Probability Event Study '.
Darj R, Grimbeek S, and Muzata G. 2011. The impact of antitrust fines on firm valuation
in South Africa: the case of Pioneer Foods, Tiger Brands and Sasol Chemical Industries,
Competition Commission of South Africa
Davies, Stephen and Peter L. Ormosi. 2012. 'A Comparative Assessment of
Methodologies used to Evaluate Competition Policy, Journal of Competition Law and
Economics (forthcoming)
Davies, Stephen and Peter L. Ormosi. 2010. 'Assessing Competition Policy:
Methodologies, Gaps and Agenda for Future Research', CCP Working Paper, 10, 19.
115
Davies, Stephen W. 2010. 'A Review of OFT's Impact Estimation methods', Office of
Fair Trading, OFT1164.
Davies, Stephen W. and Bruce Lyons. 2007. Mergers and Merger Remedies in the EU:
Assessing the Consequences for Competition, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Davies, Stephen W. and Matthew Olczak. 2008. 'An evaluation of the impact upon
productivity of ending resale price maintenance on books', Office of Fair Trading,
OFT981.
Davis, Peter and Eliana Garces. 2009. 'Quantitative Techniques for Competition and
Antitrust Analysis', Princeton University Press.
Deloitte. 2007. 'The Deterrent Effect of Competition Enforcement by the OFT', OFT962.
Deloitte 2009. Review of merger decisions under the Enterprise Act 2002, A review
prepared for the Competition Commission, the Office of Fair Trading, and the
Department for Business, Enterprise and Regulatory Reform.
Diepold, Brian, Robert Feinberg, David Round and Jeremy Tustin. 2008. 'Merger
Impacts on Investor Expectations: An Event Study for Australia', International
Journal of the Economics of Business 15, 1, 45-62.
Dobson, P. W. and C. A. Piga. 2011. The Impact of Mergers on Fares Structure:
Evidence from European Low-Cost Airlines. Economic Inquiry (forthcoming)
Donohue, J. J. and J. Wolfers. 2006. 'Uses and abuses of empirical evidence in the
death penalty debate', Stanford Law Review, 58, 791.
Duso, Tomaso, Klaus Gugler and Burcin Yurtoglu. 2010. 'Is the Event Study
Methodology Useful for Merger Analysis: A Comparison of Stock Market and
Accounting Data', International Review of Law and Economics, 30, 186-192.
Duso, Tomaso, Klaus Gugler and Burcin B. Yurtoglu. 2011. 'How Effective is
European Merger Control?', European Economic Review, 55, 7, 980-1006.
Duso, Tomaso, Damien J. Neven and Lars-Hendrik Roller. 2007. 'The Political
Economy of. European Merges Control: Evidence using Stock Market Data', Journal
of Law and Economics, 50, 455-489.
Dutz, Mark A., Ioannis Kessides, Stephen O’Connell and Robert D. Willig. 2011.
'Competition and Innovation-Driven Inclusive Growth', The World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper, WPS5852.
116
Easterbrook, F. 1992. Ignorance and Antitrust. in: Jorde, T. and D. Teece, Antitrust,
Innovation, and Competitiveness. Oxford University Press, New York/Oxford: 119136.
Eckbo, B. E. 1985. 'Mergers and the Market Concentration Doctrine: Evidence from
the Capital Market', The Journal of Business, 58, 3, 325-349.
Eckbo, B. E. 1992. 'Mergers and the Value of Antitrust Deterrence', Journal of
Finance, 47, 1005-1029.
Ehmer, C. and F. Rosati. 2009. 'Science, Myth, and Fines: Do Cartels Typically Raise
Prices by 25%?', Concurrences No 4, 1-5.
European Commission. 2011. 'Report on Competition Policy 2010', DGCOMP,
{SEC(2011) 690 final}
European Commission DGCOMP. 2010. ‘Annual Activity Report 2010’
European Commission DGCOMP. 2010. ‘DG Competition Stakeholder Study,
Aggregate Report’ at
http://ec.europa.eu/competition/publications/reports/aggregate_report_en.pdf
European Commission DGCOMP. 2005. ‘Merger Remedies Study’
Evenett, S. J. 2006. 'Competition Advocacy: Time for a rethink', Available at:
www.alexandria.unisg.ch/EXPORT/DL/Simon_Evenett/28424.pdf.
Farrell, Joseph and Carl Shapiro. 1990. 'Horizontal Mergers: An Equilibrium
Analysis', The American Economic Review, 80, 1, 107-126.
Farrell, Joseph and Carl Shapiro. 2010. 'Antitrust Evaluation of Horizontal Mergers:
An Economic Alternative to Market Definition', The B.E. Journal of Theoretical
Economics, Policies and Perspectives, 10, 1, Article 9.
Fonseca, M. A. and H.-T. Normann. 2009. 'Mergers, Asymmetries and Collusion:
Experimental Evidence', The Economic Journal, 118, 527, 387-400.
Gilbert, Robert J. 2008. Competition and Innovation. in: Collins, Wayne D., Issues in
Competition Law and Policy. ABA Section of Antitrust Law: Chapter 26.
Griffith, Rachel, Rupert Harrison and Gareth Macartney. 2006. 'Product Market
Reforms, Labour Market Institutions and Unemployment', Institute for Fiscal Studies,
WP06/06.
Haffner, Robert C.G., Stephen Nickell, Giuseppe Nicoletti, Stefano Scarpetta and
Gylfi Zoega. 2000. 'European integration, liberalisation and labour market
performance', Report for the fondazione Rudolfo DeBenedetti.
117
Harrington, J. E. 2004. 'Post-Cartel Pricing During Litigation', Journal of Industrial
Economics, 52, 517–533.
Harrington, J. 2006. The Anatomy of a Cartel Price Path: Theory Meets Practice. Keynote
Speech.
Harrington, J. E. 2008. "Optimal Corporate Leniency Programs," Journal of Industrial
Economics
Harrington, J. E. and M.H. Chang. 2009. 'Modelling the Birth and Death of Cartels
with an Application to Evaluating Antitrust Policy', Journal of the European Economic
Association, 7, 6, 1400-1435.
Hausman, J. and G. Leonard 1997 'Economic Analysis of Differentiated Products
Mergers using real world data', George Mason Law Review, 5, 3, 321-346.
Henk, Don, Kemp Ron and Sinderen Jarig. 2008. 'Measuring the Economic Effects of
Competition Law Enforcement', De Economist, 156, 4, 341-348.
Hurley, S. 2010. 'The use of surveys in merger and competition analysis', Journal of
Competition Law & Economics, 7, 1, 45–68.
Hüschelrath, Kai and Nina Leheyda. 2010. 'A Methodology for the Evaluation of
Competition Policy', ZEW Discussion Paper No.10-081.
International Competition Network. 2002. Advocacy and competition policy, report
prepared by the Advocacy Working Group, ICN’s Conference, Naples, Italy
Ivaldi, M. and F. Verboven. 2005. 'Quantifying the Effects from Horizontal Mergers
in European Competition Policy', International Journal of Industrial Organization669691.
Kemp, Ron and Jarig van Sinderen. 2008. 'Measuring the economic effects of
competition law enforcement', De Economist, 156, 4, 365-385.
Kovacic, W., R. C. Marshall, et al. 2007. Lessons for Competition Policy from the
Vitamins Cartel. in: V. Ghosal and J. Stennek, The Political Economy of Antitrust,.
Volume 282: 149-176.
Kumar, Vikram, Robert C. Marshall, Leslie M. Marx and Lily Samkharadze. 2011.
Cartel versus Merger, http://capcp.psu.edu/papers/2011/cartelvsmerger.pdf.
Kwoka J and Lawrence J. White. 2004. Antitrust Revolution: Economics, Competition,
and Policy, Oxford University Press.
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez de Silanes and Andrei Shleifer. 2008 'The
Economic Consequences of Legal Origins', Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 285-332.
118
Langus, Gregor, Massimo Motta and Luca Aguzzoni. 2010 'The effect of EU
antitrust investigations and fines on a firm's valuation', http://ftp.zew.de/pub/zewdocs/veranstaltungen/Macci/SummerInstitute/Papers/SI_Motta.pdf.
Lear 2011. The ex-post evaluation of two merger decisions, A Report prepared by Lear
for the UK Competition Commission.
Levenstein, M. and V. Suslow. 2006. 'What Determines Cartel Success?', Journal of
Economic Literature, 44, 43–95.
London Economics 2011 The Impact of Competition Interventions on Compliance and
Deterrence, Office of Fair Trading, OFT1391.
Lübbers, T. 2009. 'Is Cartelisation Profi table? A Case Study of the Rhenish
Westphalian Coal Syndicate, 1893-1913', MPI Collective Goods Preprint, No. 2009/9.
Lyons, Bruce 2009. 'Cases in European Competition Policy: The Economic Analysis',
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Majoras, D. P. 2005. 'A Dose of our Own Medicine: Applying a Cost/Benefit Analysis to
the FTC’s Advocacy Program', Available at:
www.ftc.gov/speeches/majoras/050208currebttopics.pdf.
Malkiel, B. G. 2003. 'A random walk down Wall Street : the time-tested strategy for
successful investing', New York, London, W. W. Norton.
McKinsey Global Institute 2010a. 'Beyond austerity: A path to economic growth and
renewal in Europe'.
McKinsey Global Institute 2010b. 'From austerity to prosperity: Seven priorities for the
long term in the United Kingdom'.
Meyer, D. B. 1995. Natural and Quasi-Experiments in Economics. Journal of Business
and Economic Statistics, 13, 151-161.
Meyer, Margaret A. and John Vickers. 1997 'Performance Comparisons and
Dynamic Incentives', The Journal of Political Economy, 105, 3, 547-581.
Miller Nathan H 2009. ‘Strategic Leniency and Cartel Enforcement.’ American
Economic Review, 99(3): 750–68
Mitschke, Andreas 2008. 'The influence of national competition policy on the
international competitiveness of nations: a contribution to the debate on international
competition rules', Heidelberg, Physica Verlag.
Neven, D. J. 2006. 'Competition economics and antitrust in Europe', Economic Policy,
48, 741 - 791.
119
Neven, D. and H. Zengler 2008. 'Ex-post Evaluation of Enforcement: a PrincipalAgent Perspective', De Economist, 156, 477-490.
Nevo, A. 2000. 'Mergers with Differentiated Products: the Case of the Ready-to-eat
Cereal Industry', RAND Journal of Economics, 31, 3, 395-421.
Nickell, Stephen J. 1996. 'Competition and Corporate Performance', Journal of
Political Economy, 104, 4, 724-746.
Nickell, Stephen J., Daphne Nicolitsas and Neil Dryden. 1997. 'What makes firms
perform well?', European Economic Review, 41, 783-796.
NMa. 2005. ‘Research into the Anticipation of merger Control’ at:
http://www.nmanet.nl/Images/Rapport%20Research%20into%20the%20Anticipatio
n%20of%20merger%20control_tcm16-86578.pdf).
OECD 2011 'The Impact of Trade Liberalisation on Jobs and Growth: Technical
Note', OECD Trade Policy Working Papers, 107.
OECD 2002, Roundtable on communication by competition authorities, at:
http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/20/40/2492536.pdf
OFT 2011a. ‚Positive Impact 10/11 - Consumer benefits from the OFT's work.
OFT 2011b. Competition and Growth, Office of Fair Trading, OFT1390.
OFT 2011c. "The Impact of Competition Interventions on Compliance and Deterrence",
OFT 1391
OFT 2011d. "Commentary on retail mergers", OFT 1305/CC2
OFT 2011e. Evaluating the impact of the OFT’s consumer enforcement case against
Foxtons in respect of commission terms in letting agreements, OFT1346eval
OFT 2011f. Evaluating the impact of the OFT’s 2001 abuse of dominance case against
Napp Pharmaceuticals, OFT1332
OFT 2010a. Drivers of Compliance and Non Compliance with Competition Law', Office of
Fair Trading, OFT1227.
OFT 2010b. 'Evaluation of OFT Competition Advocacy', Office of Fair Trading,
OFT866.
OFT 2010c. 'Positive Impact 09/10 Consumer benefits from the OFT's work', Office of
Fair Trading, OFT1251.
OFT 2007. Final report of the Payment Systems Task Force, OFT901
120
Ormosi, P. L. 2010. 'Merger Remedies versus Efficiency Defence: An analysis of
merging parties’ litigation strategy in EC merger cases', CCP Working Paper Series,
10-1.
Ormosi, Peter 2011. 'How Big is a Tip of the Iceberg? A Parsimonious Way to
Estimate Cartel Detection Rate', CCP Working Paper, 11-6.
OXERA 2009. 'Quantifying antitrust damages Towards non-binding guidance for courts',
Study prepared for the European Commission,
http://www.oxera.com/cmsDocuments/Quantifying%20antitrust%20damages.pdf
Parikh, Ashok and Corneliu Stirbu. 2004 'Relationship between Trade
Liberalisation, Economic Growth and Trade Balance: An Econometric
Investigation', HWWA Discussion Paper, 282.
Peters, Craig. 2006. 'Evaluating the Performance of Merger Simulation: Evidence
From the U.S. Airline Industry', Journal of Law & Economics, 49, 627–649.
Pinske, J. and M. E. Slade 2004. 'Mergers, Brand Competition, and the Price of a
Pint', European Economic Review, 48, 617-643.
Prager, R. A. 1989. 'Using stock price data to measure the effects of regulation: the
Interstate Commerce Act and the railroad industry', RAND Journal of Economics, 20,
2, 280-290.
PricewaterhouseCoopers 2005. 'Ex-post evaluation of mergers', A report prepared for
the Office of Fair Trading, Department of Trade and Industry and the Competition
Commission.
Przybyla, Marcin and Moreno Roma 2005. 'Does Product Market Competition Reduce
Inflation? Evidence from EU Countries and Sectors', European Central Bank Working
Paper Series, No.453.
Sabbatini, P. 2008. 'Assessing the impact of antitrust intervention by the Italian
Competition Authority', De Economist, 156, 491-505.
Schmidt, Klaus M. 1997. 'Managerial Incentives and Product Market Competition',
Review of Economic Studies, 64, 191-214.
Shaw, R. W. and P. Simpson 1986. 'The Persistence of Monopoly: An Investigation
of the Effectiveness of the United KingdomMonopolies Commission', The Journal of
Industrial Economics, 34, 4, 355-372.
Sidak, Gregory J. and David Teece 2009. 'Dynamic Competition in Antitrust Law',
Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 5, 4, 581–631.
121
Sidak, S.G. 2003. 'The Failure of Good Intentions: The Worldcom Fraud and the
Collapse of American Telecommunications After Deregulation', Yale Journal on
Regulation, 20, 207-265.
Simpson, J. D. and D. Hosken. 1998. 'Are Retailing Mergers Anticompetitive? An Event
Study Analysis', Federal Trade Commission, WP-216.
Simpson, J. S. 2008. 'Difference-in-Differences Analysis in Antitrust: A Cautionary
Note', Antitrust Law Journal, 75, 623.
Sivadasan, Jagadeesh 2009. 'Barriers to Competition and Productivity: Evidence
from India', The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 9, 1.
Slade, Margaret 2008. The effects of vertical restraints: an evidence based approach.
The pros and cons of vertical restraints. Swedish Competition Authority, Stockholm.
Symeonidis, George 2002. 'The effects of competition: cartel policy and the evolution of
strategy and structure in British industry', Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press.
Tenn, S. and J. M. Yun 2010. 'The success of divestitures in merger enforcement:
Evidence from the J&J–Pfizer transaction', International Journal of Industrial
Organization, Forthcoming.
Tussie, Diana and Carlos Aggio 2006. 'Economic and social impacts of trade
liberalization', UNCTAD.
UK Competition Commission 2009. ‘Stakeholder Research 2009: A research report
prepared for The Competition Commission’ at:
http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/+/http://www.competitioncommission.org.uk/our_role/analysis/evaluation_reports.htm
UK Competition Commission 2010. ‘Understanding past merger remedies: report on
case study research’
USDoJ. 2012. Antitrust Division’s Performance Budget Congressional Submission for
2008-2011, at: http://www.justice.gov/jmd/2012justification/pdf/fy12-atrjustification.pdfand
UK Competition Commission 2008. 'Evaluation of the Competition Commission’s past
cases'.
USFTC 1999. ‘A Study of the Commission's Divestiture Process’
USFTC 2011. ‘Performance and Accountability Report 2011 and earlier years, at:
http://www.ftc.gov/opp/gpra/2011parreport.pdf
122
Verboven, F. and T. Van Dijk (2009) 'Cartel damages claims and the passing-on
defence', Journal of Industrial Economics, 57, 3, 457-491(435).
Warren-Boulton, Frederick R. and Serdar Dalkir 2001. 'Staples and Office Depot: An
Event-Probability Case Study', Review of Industrial Organization, 19, 4, 467.
Weinberg, Matthew 2007. 'The Price Effects of Horizontal Mergers: A Survey', CEPS
Working Paper, No. 140.
Werden, G. J. 2000. 'Expert Report in United States v. Interstate Bakeries Corp. and
Continental Baking Co.', International Journal of the Economics of Business, 7, 2, 139148.
Werden, G., A. Joskow and R. Johnson 1991. 'The Effects of Mergers on Price and
Output: Two Case Studies from the Airline Industry', Managerial and Decision
Economics, 12, 341–352.
Werden, Gregory J. 2008. 'Assessing the Effects of Antitrust Enforcement in the
United States', De Economist, 156, 4, 433–451.
Werden, Gregory J. and Luke M Froeb 1994. 'The Effects of Mergers in
Differentiated Products Industries: Logit Demand and Merger Policy', Journal of
Law, Economics and Organization, 10, 2, 407-426.
Whinston, Michael and Scott Collins 1992. 'Entry and Competitive Structure in
Deregulated Airline Markets: An Event Study Analysis of People Express', The Rand
Journal of Economics, 23, 445-462.
World Economic Forum 2002. 'The Global Competitiveness Report 2001-2002', Oxford
University Press.
Zheng, Shilin and Michael R. Ward 2011. 'The Effects of Market Liberalization and
Privatization on Chinese Telecommunications', China Economic Review,
(forthcoming).
Adress 103 85 Stockholm
Telefon 08-700 16 00
Fax 08-24 55 43
[email protected]