Framework Performance Assessment
Transcription
Framework Performance Assessment
THE LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE Framework Performance Assessment November 2006 Elias Mossialos, Sara Allin and Joy Ladurner With: Daniel Hentschel, Kitty Lawrence, Anita Rieder, Caroline Rudisill, Corinna Sorenson, and Charitini Stavropoulou Please do not cite without consent of the authors. Suggested citation: Mossialos, E., Allin, S., Ladurner, J. et al. 2006. Framework Performance Assessment. Report for the Main Association of Austrian Social Security Institutions. London: LSE Health and Social Care Contents EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 1. OVERVIEW 1.1 Methodology 4 11 15 2. DISTRIBUTION OF COSTS AND BENEFITS IN THE POPULATION 2.1 Funding health care 18 18 2.1.2 Spending on health care in Austria 2.2 Sources of funding 2.2.1 Sources of funding in Austria 2.3 Defining benefits and beneficiaries 2.3.1 Defining benefits in the Austrian health system (what is covered?) 2.3.2 Defining beneficiaries in the Austrian health system (who is covered?) 2.3.3 The e-card 2.4 Progressivity of financing 2.4.1 Progressivity of financing in the Austrian health system 3. ACCESS TO HEALTH CARE SERVICES 3.1 Analysis of European Community Household Panel 3.2 Analysis of SHARE survey – equity in use of services among over 50 population in Europe 3.3 Access to care and cost sharing 3.4 Access to care and voluntary health insurance 3.5 Access to care for asylum seekers, refugees and illegal immigrants 3.6 Geographical access to care 3.7 Barriers to access health services in Austria 3.7.1 Financial barriers 3.7.2 Geographical barriers 3.7.3 Cultural barriers 3.7.4 Barriers in accessing preventive health services 3.7.5 Inequalities in utilization of health services in Austria 3.7.6 Measures to improve access to care in Austria 3.8 Patient pathways 3.8.1 Patient pathway in Austria 4. REGULATION OF THE HEALTH SYSTEM 4.1 Performance indicators 4.2 Regulating the health system in Austria 4.2.1 Independent monitoring agencies 4.2.2 Extent of decentralization of regulatory functions 4.2.3 Regulating purchasing 4.3.5 Regulating provision 5. ALLOCATIVE EFFICIENCY AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION 5.1 Health technology assessment 5.1.1 HTA in Austria 5.2 Resource allocation in Austria 5.2.1 Decisions about the health care budget 5.2.2 Allocation of budgets 5.2.3 Decisions about capital investments 5.2.4 Hospital planning 5.2.5 Geographical differences in per capita health expenditures 6. TECHNICAL EFFICIENCY 6.1 Administrative costs 6.1.2 Administrative costs in Austria 6.2 Physical and human resources 6.2.1 Hospital capacity in Austria 6.2.2 Substitution policies in Austria LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 22 24 28 30 32 34 38 43 47 54 55 60 65 65 66 67 71 71 75 75 75 78 82 93 93 97 98 100 102 104 107 113 124 126 130 131 132 132 133 133 134 136 136 137 139 141 143 2 6.2.3 Physician career paths in Austria 6.3 Provider payment methods 6.3.1 Provider payment methods in Austria 6.4 Continuity of care 6.4.1 Continuity of care in Austria 7. QUALITY OF CARE 7.1 Appropriateness of care 7.1.1 Quality of care in Austria 7.2 Patient safety and medical errors 7.2.1 Patient safety in Austria 7.2.2 Patient rights in Austria 7.3 Patient choice 7.3.1 Choice in the Austrian health system 7.4 Satisfaction with health care 7.4.1 Patient satisfaction in Austria 7.5 Inter-generational solidarity: caring for older people 8. CONTRIBUTION OF THE HEALTH SYSTEM TO HEALTH IMPROVEMENT 8.1 Trends in life expectancy in Europe 8.2 Avoidable mortality 8.3 Trends in chronic diseases in Europe 8.4 Screening programs 8.4.1 Prevention and screening programs in Austria 8.5 Health inequalities 8.6 Health trends in Austria 8.6.1 Obesity and overweight 8.6.2 Tobacco consumption 8.6.3 Alcohol 8.6.4 Poverty and health 8.6.5 Socio-economic status and health 8.6.6 Evidence on measures of mortality amenable to medical intervention: variation across regions 8.6.7 Factors contributing to changes in health status 8.6.8 Are these factors related to health care, public health, health policy, lifestyle or other aspects 8.7 Health targets in Austria 145 146 150 155 157 159 159 161 168 173 178 182 185 191 195 200 201 201 203 208 214 217 225 230 234 237 238 239 241 242 247 249 251 8.7.1 National health targets 8.7.2 Regional health care goals 8.7.3 Targets in Social Insurance 251 253 253 9. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 9.1 Options for research 255 266 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 3 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Performance assessment in health care has become a goal of national and international bodies in recent years. Aggregate measures of performance, such as the WHO World Health Report rankings, fail to identify strengths and weaknesses of health systems. This report adopts the perspective of health system functions in order to provide a more comprehensive and policy-relevant evaluation focusing on: financing, distribution of costs and benefits, access to care, regulatory capacity, resource allocation, technical efficiency and payment methods, quality and satisfaction, and health improvement. 1. Financing health care: levels, sources, and progressivity of funding Recent years have witnessed significant increases in health spending, in some countries at a faster rate than GDP, due to increases in labour costs, technological innovation, rising public expectations, pressures from providers, and population ageing. At present, average health spending in the EU is 8.6% of GDP, with a range from 6% in Poland and Slovakia to 11% in Germany. In the European region, public sources of financing (taxation or social health insurance) comprise the bulk of expenditure, ranging from 51% in Greece to 90% in Czech Republic. The bulk of private payments stems from out-of-pocket payments; ranging between 20% in the Netherlands and 40% in France to over 90% of private expenditure in Greece, Denmark and the Slovak Republic. Financing reform has been seen in some countries, e.g. France – in 1998, social insurance contributions expanded to include total income rather than solely wages; with similar discussions taking place in Germany. Calculations of health expenditure in Austria have been the focus of longstanding debate. Until recently calculations of health spending has followed a system of national accounts – which led to an estimation of total health spending to be 7.5% of GDP in 2004. However with the new system of health accounts (OECD), estimates for total spending in 2004 are much higher at 9.6% of GDP. This revised estimate places Austria above the average spending in the EU. The mean annual growth rate over the past ten years was lower than the EU average, at 6.3% compared to 6.9%. With regards to the proportion of total spending that derives from public sources, the level in Austria is lower than the majority of EU countries. Indeed, the share of private funding is about 30%, which places Austria 3rd highest in the EU 15 and 9th highest among 30 OECD countries. The public sources of funding in Austria consist of statutory social insurance (45% of total spending), and 25% from general and value-added taxation (which is mainly directed towards hospital payments). On the other hand, the private sources of funding consist largely of out-of-pocket payments – both indirect (13.5%) and direct (7.6%) user charges. Private health insurance plays only a minor role in the financing of health care in Austria, constituting 2.4% of total health expenditure. Progressivity of financing refers to the extent to which individuals on higher income are contributing relatively more than those on lower income. Taxation tends to be more progressive than social health insurance (SHI). However, while direct taxes are progressive, indirect taxes (e.g. VAT) are regressive. Furthermore, having fewer tax bands and low marginal tax rates makes the system more regressive. Out-ofpocket payments are regressive, however exemption mechanisms can reduce the financial burden on those least able to pay. In Austria there have not been any comprehensive studies on the level of progressivity in the financing of health care; however, some evidence exists. For instance, inequality of wage income in the country appears to be increasing, however the state plays a role in redistributing from the wealthy to the poor in the form of social and health care related transfer payments. Analysis of the progressivity of the funding components suggest that taxes are progressive up to income threshold (maximal tax rate up to 50% for self-employed and 44% for employed), then regressive. Similarly, SHI contributions are progressive up to the earnings threshold for chargeable contributions (€ 3,750 per month in 2006), then regressive. It is important to note, however, that wages and the wage quota are declining, which is resulting in an erosion of the SHI funding base. Further exacerbating the financial constraint is the observation that SHI spending is increasing at a faster rate than revenue through SHI contributions. The other large component of financing is user charges, which are regressive. However, there are extensive exemption mechanisms in place that generally are based on income level and illness categories, but few specifically for children. The financing system in Austria, LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 4 however, allows many forms of redistribution, thus contributing to fair financing: between generations, income groups, healthy to sick individuals, and insured single persons to insured with dependants. 2. Access to care: barriers to access and equitable utilization Almost all European countries provide universal or near-universal coverage to statutory health insurance, a precondition for access. However, barriers to access exist – e.g. financial, geographical, cultural, administrative – and are unequally distributed across the population, where lower socioeconomic groups tend to experience greater barriers to access than their better off comparators. Furthermore, barriers to access may be especially pronounced for asylum seekers and refugees. There is considerable variation across Europe in reported barriers to access. For instance, waiting times for elective surgery exist in some countries (mainly tax-funded) more than others (mainly SHI funded). Furthermore, some countries appear to have more inequitable access in terms of geographic proximity to health facilities than others. Results of two comprehensive analyses of survey data (European Community Household Panel Survey (ECHP); and Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe (SHARE)) are reported, both measuring the extent to which equity in utilization – i.e. equal use of services for equal need – is achieved. Overall, it appears there is no evidence of inequity, or in some cases pro-poor inequity in primary care (GP services) in Europe. On the contrary, there appears to be significant pro-rich inequity in specialist services in almost all European countries analysed. This means that higher income groups are more likely to access specialist care than lower income groups, after standardizing for differences in need (health status). Finally, it appears there is little evidence of inequity, or in some cases pro-rich inequity, in hospital (inpatient care). For inpatient care, the probability of admission is measured and not the number of separate hospital admissions. In Austria, like the rest of Europe, statutory health insurance covers almost the entire population (97.8%), with insurance contributions based on ability to pay and not health risk. However, barriers to access are still present, e.g. geographical barriers (for instance in rural areas there is limited access to some specialist services), cultural or language barriers, difficulties faced by people with disabilities in accessing care, and differences in level of information about entitlements across population groups. Furthermore, regional variations exist in the utilization of services and health spending per capita, however more research is needed to better understand reasons for these differences. Analysis of ECHP and SHARE reveal that in Austria, GP services appear equitable or pro-poor (depending on the survey), while specialist services and, to a less extent inpatient care, are pro-rich. With the aim at reducing barriers to accessing care and improving equity in access, a number of initiatives have been introduced. For example, opening hours of contract physicians have been extended, translation services are offered for migrants, initiatives to raise awareness of insured population of entitlements have been provided through insurance fund-led facilities. In addition to the above-mentioned barriers to access, financial barriers in the form of direct and indirect user charges exist in most European countries. User charges for physician visits are present in Austria, France, Greece, Italy, Sweden and Switzerland; and for pharmaceuticals in all countries. User charges for inpatient care are less common. In Austria and Germany, there is a co-payment per day of around €8-9, with exemptions after 14 days in Germany and 28 days in Austria. Furthermore, where voluntary health insurance (VHI) offers faster access to public services (supplementary insurance), individuals who can afford to purchase VHI may be receiving better access than lower income earners. In Austria, user charges do not seem to be significant barrier because of exemptions for low-income groups and individuals with diseases incurring high treatment costs. It should however be noted that user charges are not aligned meaning there is no upper limit which takes all user charges into consideration, e.g. per person per time period (Moreover, analysis of SHARE show that a low proportion of individuals (<3%) forego care because of costs (among 50+ population) in comparison to other European countries. However, there is no blanket exemption for children, except for prescription charges; they are only exempt from user charges on some specific occasions. Inequalities across employment groups exist because of (slight) differences in benefits packages across insurance funds, and varying levels of cost sharing across insurance funds. Furthermore, while waiting times in Austria is not a significant issue for emergency treatment they do exist for elective care. Data on waiting times are very scarce and usually not available to the public. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 5 Higher income groups may get faster access to elective treatment through voluntary health insurance coverage. 3. Regulatory capacity Regulation involves many functions and takes place at many levels of the health system. There are three principle models of organizational relationship between purchasers and providers: (1) integrated; (2) contract; and (3) direct payment to providers. Government may play a regulatory role at national, regional and district levels; many countries have independent monitoring agencies (e.g. UK). Also regulatory functions may be the responsibility of independent non-governmental- or arms-length bodies. There is a general continuum of state authority and supervision that ranges from: command-and-control (e.g. NHS trusts in the UK; public hospitals in Austria and Germany), to arms-length approaches such as private notfor-profit entities with statutory responsibilities (e.g. sickness funds) and private-for-profit companies with or without service agreements with public payers (e.g. private hospitals in Italy and Portugal). One specific regulatory function – health technology assessment (HTA) – is increasingly a part of national prioritysetting; almost all EU countries have established HTA programs; these can be either advisory or regulatory. In Austria, all three models of service provision can be seen. For example, social insurance funds have integrated institutions (e.g. rehabilitation clinics), contracts are used for primary and secondary care; and private payment exists for services outside of the SHI benefits package. One serious challenge in Austria is the fragmentation of responsibilities for funding and provision of services, especially for secondary care. Although regulation is strongly based on federal (and some state) legislation (in the SHI system, the Federation defines rules and insurance funds implement them and purchase services), regulatory functions are largely decentralized. Thus, Government relies heavily on delegation of regulatory functions and devolution to federal states, for example in the case of hospital care. As seen in the rest of Europe, HTA is increasingly being used for decision-making; however, further elaboration of HTA activities should be encouraged. 4. Allocative efficiency and resource allocation Allocative efficiency refers to the extent to which the amounts and types of health services are efficient and maximize health gain. Health expenditure by sector is one indication, although crude, of allocative efficiency. For instance, while increasing expenditure in some sectors like pharmaceuticals should correspond to improved health outcomes, it is difficult to measure the extent to which this is the case. High levels of spending in inpatient care may be seen as inefficient and reflecting deficiencies in lower levels of the system. Furthermore, spending on primary care and prevention, the most cost effective care, is very low in most countries (including Austria). Methods of resource allocation have moved away from historical and retrospective reimbursement towards fixed fee schedules, budgets, and activity-based payments. Capitation with risk adjustment is increasingly common in Europe; risk adjustment formulae are developed in order to compensate purchasers (health plans; sickness funds) with high risk/high cost patients and avoid risk selection in countries with competition among funds (e.g. Germany, the Netherlands) or reduce geographic inequalities in health care (e.g. United Kingdom). In Austria there is considerable fragmentation in sources of funding, especially for hospital care. Further contributing to inefficiency is the fact that resource allocation remains mostly based on historical patterns. With the aim at improving efficiency and continuity of care, recently more cooperation between primary and secondary care has been promoted; but budget insecurity still exist (Reform pool1). Planning resource allocation is one method of improving allocative efficiency. In Austria while instruments for resource planning exist, including mandatory quality standards; they are not yet covering all areas of care. Recently the scheme for risk adjustment between funds was revised to incorporate characteristics of insured population (e.g. average costs, revenue generated by prescriptions charges, extraordinarily high cost 1 Will funds of the recently established reform pool really be available and used? LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 6 patients). While this is a positive change, follow-up activities will be necessary: an evaluation of the actual impact of this change is needed along with further improvements and refinements to the risk adjustment formula. 5. Technical efficiency Technical efficiency means producing the maximum possible sustained output from a given set of inputs. Many factors influence technical efficiency including: administrative costs, supply and payment of providers, and continuity of care. On average, administrative costs tend to be lower in tax-funded systems, and Austria appears to be keeping costs down compared to other SHI systems (3.6% of total health spending in Austria; 4-6% in Netherlands and Germany). Higher levels of high-cost equipment (e.g. hightech diagnostics) and providers (e.g. doctors versus nurses) may create inefficiencies. Substitution policies may serve to increase efficiency as well, for example between doctors and nurses, or using generic instead of brand name prescriptions. Hospital efficiency can be inferred from average length of stay, which has been declining significantly across Europe in recent years. Ensuring continuity of care may improve quality of care and efficiency, for example by reducing consultation times, making better clinical decisions. In Austria, there have been only few studies on productivity using data envelopment analysis for hospital care, however more research is needed. There is a relatively high level of resources relative to other countries; a high number of hospital beds per capita, although this has reduced over recent years; and a high number of high technology diagnostics (CT and MRI scanners) per capita compared to other European countries. It is unclear to what extent this high capacity is excessive and inefficient. It seems hospital efficiency appears to be improving since introduction of DRG payment system, as indicated by low average length of stay and reduction in acute care beds. However the number of inpatient-admissions has gone up constantly since 1991 whereby the increase has been stronger after the introduction of the performance related reimbursement system, the socalled LKF system (especially in hospitals not funded by the federal health funds). This is partially rooted in the increase in day-clinic cases as well as case-splitting. Increases in costs were contained by capping expenditures. It is important, however, that monitoring of potential cost-shifting and gaming of the system (“DRG creep”) is undertaken. Other areas of potential inefficiency in Austria relate to incentive structures such as the lack of selective contracting of physicians, the fact that generic prescribing is not encouraged, generic substitution by pharmacists is not permitted and pharmacist payment methods do not encourage the dispensing of lower cost drugs. Continuity of care in Austria is quite limited at present. This relative lack of continuity can be attributed to numerous causes such as: different funding streams and responsibilities for health and social services; duplication of services in primary and secondary care (although it is encouraging that the acceptance of laboratory tests done at primary care level by hospital physicians seems to be increasing); variation in clinical processes in the absence of clinical guidelines, lack of standards (e.g. for care in general or with regards to checking patients out of hospitals); the only recent development of disease management programs (which is solely for diabetes at present); and extensive choice of provider. Finally, there may be excessive referrals between providers taking place in order to remain within certain limits defined by insurance funds, such as with regards to the number of prescriptions. With respect to long term care more than 350,000 individuals in Austria are in need of daily care2, and the number is constantly increasing. There is a considerable demand for qualified nursing staff as well as standards for long term care. Currently staff needs are partially met by illegal carers from Eastern Europe; this fact became an important topic during the election campaign of 2006. While as a short term solution the employment of illegal carers in private households is not being reported, long term solutions are being discussed. 2 Federal Ministry of Social Insurance, Generations and Consumer Protection (2005). Introduction, orientation guide on the topic of disability, Vienna LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 7 Provider payment methods have significant implications for technical efficiency. Physicians are paid on a fee-for-service basis in many countries (Austria, Belgium, France and Germany); while this method encourages increases in productivity, it may lead to unnecessary cost escalation and supplier-induced demand. Moreover, payment based on activity and without targets for quality or performance may limit the influence of payers on quality of care. Hospital payment is increasingly based on activity in Europe, with many countries using DRGs (diagnosis-related groups). In Austria, physicians are paid mainly on the basis of fee-for-service, which is supplemented by capitation. In light of the cost-escalating potential of fee-for-service payments, various mechanisms for cost control have been introduced such as price -volume adjustments after a certain threshold is met. Fee structures of most insurance funds include quality criteria for service provision though funds have limited scope to demand and monitor quality of providers and services. Incentives are part of the general contract or fee structures, although there is still limited use to date, and a relative lack of evaluation of impacts. Hospitals are paid on the basis of an activity – DRG (LKF) system dating back to 1997 – which covers about half of hospital payments. This system increases transparency and provides hospitals with the incentive to improve efficiency, but there is a need to monitor potential upcoding practices. 6. Quality of care Quality of care is extremely difficult to measure, although some indicators include medical errors, patient satisfaction, and level of support for patient safety and patient rights. Patient choice, which can be for insurance, provider, or treatment, is often associated with quality and patient satisfaction. In Europe, satisfaction with health care varies quite a lot; Austria appears to have among the highest levels of satisfaction with the health system/health care and perceived quality of care. Choice of provider is perceived to be very high in Belgium, Switzerland, France, Germany, Denmark, Ireland and Austria - and low in Iceland, Portugal and Ukraine. With the aim to improve quality, quality assurance and patient safety initiatives have been introduced in many countries, such as clinical guidelines. Furthermore, efforts to monitor prescribing patterns and establish national patient safety programs have been seen in many countries. Medical errors, another indication of quality, represent a significant cost and health burden in Europe. Surveys reveal citizens in some countries perceive medical errors to be more of a concern (e.g. in Greece, Poland, the UK, Slovenia) than others (e.g. Austria and Sweden); and are more confident in their doctors in some countries (e.g. Austria and France). Overall in Austria, perceptions of quality of care are quite high. For instance, there appears to be consistently high satisfaction with health care and public services. Also, choice of provider is very high, but very limited choice of insurance fund exists, and choice of physician in hospital is mainly restricted to private hospitals. Efforts are needed to maintain the current level of quality and satisfaction, and there is a need to develop and monitor quality indicators. Many quality-related activities have been initiated; however, at present they are only partially implemented. Although it seems the population is on the whole satisfied in Austria, insurance funds have very limited possibility of monitoring and improving quality of providers and care. Furthermore, providers are not subject to re-validation of their skills. The quality of services provided by physicians in their practices is currently only evaluated by means of self-assessment. Evaluation is organized by the ÖQmed Company which is owned by the Austrian Medical Association. Regarding patient safety, there is currently no national body for patient safety to set standards, and, until recently, no legal basis for reporting medical errors existed. Finally, there is no information on quality of providers reported to public. Austria has issued a Patient Charter which has been signed by all federal states. Patients can seek advice from patient lawyers, ombudsmen and other institutions protecting patient rights. In 2006 the Advance Directive Act was issued enabling patients to set up an advance directive. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 8 7. Health outcomes Health gains have been seen in all European countries in terms of life expectancy and infant mortality. However, all across Europe, the prevalence of obesity is increasing, and while overall smoking levels and related deaths have declined in most countries, among certain population groups such as youths and women, this is not the case. In Austria, life expectancy at birth is higher than the EU average and appears to be increasing. In 1980, female life expectancy was ranked 11th in the EU, which has increased to 7th in 2003; for men the same trend was seen with a change in ranking from 14th to 9th. These improvements have largely been attributed to reductions in infant mortality due to better quality care and improved living conditions. As with other European countries, there appears to be a worsening in the case of some important risk factors. For instance, obesity is on the rise for all age groups, but especially for children and young people. Tobacco consumption also appears to be increasing among Austrian women, but falling for men. Moreover, smoking prevalence for teenagers is one of the highest among European countries (age 15: 26% of girls, 20% of boys smoke daily). Finally, alcohol is a serious health problem; death rate due to cirrhosis of the liver is among the highest in Europe. It is possible to disentangle overall levels of health between those that are attributed to the health care system, and those that are not. The concept of avoidable mortality, or deaths that should be avoided in the presence of timely and effective medical care, sheds some light on the strengths and weaknesses of the health system in leading to health improvement. Evidence suggests there has been better progress in treatable than preventable diseases in Austria. This may reflect the curative focus of the health system in Austria, and only recent prioritization of prevention. However, more research is needed to update the current evidence base which draws from data in the 1990s, and to generate information on a regional basis within Austria to determine whether any regional differences exist in the functioning of the health system. For example, to date, screening programs are limited; they are only opportunistic although a national mammography screening program will be introduced shortly. 8. Conclusions By adopting the performance assessment framework that identifies the objectives and functions of the health system, the Austrian health system appears to have both strengths and limitations. There is a relatively high degree of trust, confidence, choice, and satisfaction among the Austrian population. Further, there appear to be several positive developments in recent years, such as to the implementation of a performance based hospital payment system, the introduction of an electronic health card (e-card), the development of a diabetes management program, and national mammography screening program. These developments could all lead to improvements in equity and efficiency. Despite these strengths, there are some lessons that can be learned from examining the system more closely and drawing comparisons with other countries. Continuity of care in Austria could be improved. Disease management programs could be extended to include other disease areas following an evaluation of the diabetes initiative. Research could be done to identify high service users and then assigning them to a personal doctor or clinical team. Clinical information could be better shared across areas and levels of care. Finally, although high levels of patient choice of provider are valued by the population, one may consider questioning the extent to which this current level compromises continuity of care. Public health and prevention activities appear to be gaining in importance in Austria. This is a positive step towards shifting care from high cost to lower and cost-effective care. Spending on inpatient care in Austria appears quite high relative to other countries, therefore reflecting possible inefficiencies at lower levels. Furthermore, the new mammography screening program should be evaluated for effectiveness and costeffectiveness, and extensions to other disease areas should be considered based on this evaluation and international evidence. The new health check-up program also reflects the increasing importance paid to prevention; however, this should also be subject to monitoring and evaluation. Furthermore, as the health LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 9 trends indicate emerging and persistent health threats such as alcohol consumption, obesity, and smoking, particularly among young people, more research is needed to develop national surveys focusing on these areas, and to initiate public health programs targeting population groups, such as youths, and those most at risk. Finally, in light of the ageing population, prevention and care programs aimed at elderly people, particularly those living alone, should be developed. Quality of care appears to be perceived as quite high by the population, therefore efforts are needed to maintain this high level. Also, additional quality indicators and standardized measures of waiting times could be developed and released to the public, in order to increase transparency and empower patients, which may lead to efficiency improvements. Research into avoidable mortality which provides an indication of the quality and overall performance of health care should be updated and perhaps conducted on a regional level, thus highlighting variation in performance within the country. The risk equalization scheme of social health insurance represents an important step towards ensuring equity in the financing of the health system. However, this scheme should be evaluated, and possibly elaborated to better reflect need. Moreover, research investigating regional variations in access to care, costs and health outcomes would be beneficial. Awareness for gender medicine is only gradually arising in Austria, it will be beneficial to place more importance on this issue in the future. The current supply of health services appears in some cases sufficient (for instance regarding hospital beds and advanced diagnostic equipment) but relatively low in other cases (e.g. regarding the number of nurses, especially for long term care). Research assessments on the current needs and also projections of future human resources need should be undertaken. Payment of professionals appears in some cases to incentivise productivity (e.g. fee-for-service arrangements for physicians and DRG-type system for hospitals) however, these schemes should be evaluated in terms of impacts on costs and outcomes, and further incentives may be considered to be elaborated, such as by including quality targets in the payments system and revising pharmacist payments to remove the link to the cost of prescriptions. A special fund for research could be set up drawing on funds from federal and state government and insurance funds that is at an arms-length from government. Further, an institute could commission work to local institutions such as universities and research centers in order to address key research areas. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 10 1. OVERVIEW Modern health systems developed out of concern for social protection and equity. Health insurance systems arose in many countries in the late nineteenth century, through mutual aid societies or sickness funds that covered some workers. After the Second World War, there was a major emphasis across the developed world on expanding health insurance coverage driven in part by advances in medical care such as penicillin and antibiotics, alongside the election of quasi-socialist governments with the aim to better protect their citizens.3 The first post-war health reform was in the United Kingdom with the Beveridge Report of 1942, leading to the National Health Service (NHS) Act and its implementation in 1948. Shortly thereafter the Japanese, Canadian and French systems were formed (1958-1961), followed by Italy and Germany. At present all OECD countries offer (near) universal health care coverage of the population with the exception of Turkey and the United States. The public systems that were set up were relatively generous, with comprehensive baskets of health services, little cost-sharing, and few controls on health care demand and supply.4 Since the 1970s, spending on health care grew more quickly than governments could easily afford, due to the limited constraints on spending and growing technical sophistication of medical practice. As a response, there was a gradual shift away from ensuring the generosity and equality of coverage to cost containment in large part by introducing tighter regulatory mechanisms5. For instance, in the hospital sector, countries that relied on global budgets restricted the budgetary limits with some countries introducing activity-based payments (e.g. in Italy). For physicians, cost containment measures consisted of tightening the fee schedules and introducing prescription drug budgets (e.g. in Germany). Despite some success in putting downward pressure on increasing health expenditures in many countries, these cost-containment policies, alongside the rationed model associated with it, became less popular for many reasons. In summary, these reforms were associated with: increased difficulties in accessing care, such as long waiting lists; a lack of incentives to increase efficiency; and only short-term cost savings.6 Therefore, more recently a new wave of health reform emerged focussing on introducing incentives to improve efficiency largely by: a) increasing cost sharing, b) introducing competition between insurance funds, c) separating purchasing from provision (e.g. the purchaser-provider split in the United Kingdom), and d) reforming payment mechanisms; by now almost all European countries operate some form of diagnostic related group (DRG) funding mechanism. Continuing pressures on health systems worldwide stem from the conflicts between the goals of efficiency and equity which becomes more complicated as the cost of health care continues to rise.7 Measuring health care performance Health care system performance is currently a high priority on international and national policy agendas. However the concern with measuring the performance of health systems dates back to the 1800s. In fact, Florence Nightingale in the 1860s initiated the practice of comparing hospital outcomes data with the aim to better understand and improve performance. Only in the last decade or so has the vision of making use of large-scale data sources to measure and improve health system performance been realised. Performance 3 D.M. Cutler, "Equality, Efficiency, and Market Fundamentals: The Dynamics of International Medical-Care Reform," Journal of Economics Literature XL (2002). 4 J.P Newhouse, "Medical Care Costs: How Much Welfare Loss?," Journal of Economics Perspectives 6, no. 3 (1992). 5 Cutler, "Equality, Efficiency, and Market Fundamentals: The Dynamics of International Medical-Care Reform.", E Mossialos and J Le Grand, eds., Health Care and Cost Containment in the European Union (Ashgate: Aldershot, 1999). 6 Cutler, "Equality, Efficiency, and Market Fundamentals: The Dynamics of International Medical-Care Reform." 7 Ibid. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 11 data serve broadly two purposes: to identify what works to achieve the health system objectives; and to identify specific areas of competence.8 Following the publication of the World Health Report by WHO in 2000 which yielded a ranking of health systems in 191 countries, most governments have been concerned with the measurement of their own health system’s performance and comparing strengths and weaknesses with other countries. One of the major criticisms of any approach to measure performance based on aggregate data is that they provide little or no indication of what needs to be done to improve the system when faced with evidence of sub-optimal performance. It is vital that more detailed analyses of the components of health care systems is conducted in order to disentangle the specific issues that warrant attention. The World Health Report provides a useful starting point for measuring health system performance. This report outlines three fundamental dimensions of performance: health attainment as measured by healthy (or disability-free) life expectancy, responsiveness to the needs of the population, and fairness of financing. The report further delineates four functions through which countries can achieve these three goals: service provision, resource generation, financing, and stewardship. On the basis of these components, health care systems of different countries are ranked: France came out as the best performing health system in the world; Austria was ranked 9th (5th in the EU) (see Table 1.1). One of the major contributions of this report was the development of an instrument to assess health systems’ responsiveness to the population based on seven dimensions: autonomy, confidentiality, dignity, prompt attention, quality of basic amenities, access to social support networks during care, and choice of providers. While as a concept this is clearly important to consider when evaluating a country’s health system, these indicators are incredibly difficult to measure, and even more difficult to compare across countries. In light of the limited data to measure these concepts, WHO methodology consisted of surveys of a selection of informants in 35 of the 191 countries, with imputation methods used for the remaining countries. Table 1.1 Top 25 countries in WHO rankings by health status and health system performance Rank Countries ranked by Countries ranked by health health status system performance 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 Oman Malta Italy France San Marino Spain Andorra Jamaica Japan Saudi Arabia Greece Monaco Portugal Singapore Austria United Arab Emirates Morocco Norway France Italy San Marino Andorra Malta Singapore Spain Oman Austria Japan Norway Portugal Monaco Greece Iceland Luxembourg Netherlands United Kingdom 8 P Smith, ed., Measuring Up: Improving Health System Performance in OECD Countries (Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2002). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 12 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 Netherlands Solomon Islands Sweden Cyprus Chile United Kingdom Costa Rica Ireland Switzerland Belgium Colombia Sweden Cyprus Germany Source: WHO World Health Report 2000 The findings of the World Health Report were highly controversial and led to widespread international criticism. Critics argued the choice and measurement of specific indicators was flawed, there were doubts about the reliability of the data used, debates over how the various indicators should be weighted, and identified other problems related to the methodology.9 Furthermore, a large part of the analysis derived from expert opinion, and indeed public opinion and satisfaction with the system appear to deviate significantly from the WHO rankings.10 A Canadian non-profit organization, the Conference Board, recently undertook a benchmark analysis of 24 OECD countries looking at three categories of performance: health status, non-medical factors and health outcomes, each with their own set of indicators.11 Health status indicators include life expectancy, disability-free life-expectancy, self-reported health status, infant mortality rates, and low birth weight. Nonmedical factors consist of body weight, tobacco and alcohol consumption, road traffic accidents, sulphur oxide emissions, and immunizations (DPT and influenza). Finally, health outcomes are comprised of mortality rates from lung cancer, acute myocardial infarction, stroke, suicide, and potential years of life lost (PYLL) through suicide (male), lung cancer, and breast cancer. To aid interpretation, they categorise each country as either gold, silver or bronze based on their relative position. The ranking of performance based on the three indicators is seen in Table 1.2. Table 1.2 Ranking of a selection of OECD countries based on Canada’s Conference Board health system performance indicator system (rank based on weighted average of indicators) Rank Country Gold Silver Bronze 1 Switzerland 14 9 1 2 Sweden 14 7 0 3 Spain 12 9 3 4 France 12 9 2 5 Italy 11 11 0 6 Germany 9 15 0 7 Norway 13 6 2 8 Japan 14 3 7 9 Iceland 12 7 2 10 Australia 10 11 3 11 Netherlands 11 9 4 12 Finland 11 7 4 13 Canada 7 13 4 14 Mexico 12 4 4 15 Belgium 9 8 4 9 C Almeida et al., "Methodological Concerns and Recommendations on Policy Consequences of the World Health Report 2000," Lancet 357, no. 9269 (2001). 10 RJ Blendon, Kim, M, Benson, JM, "The Public Versus the World Health Organization on Health System Performance," Health Affairs 20, no. 3 (2001). 11 The Conference Board of Canada, "Understanding Health Care Cost Drivers and Escalators," (Ottawa: The Conference Board of Canada, 2004). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 13 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 New Zealand Austria Denmark Korea Portugal United Kingdom Ireland United States Greece 7 6 8 9 8 6 7 5 5 12 13 8 5 7 11 7 9 8 5 3 6 9 5 7 7 10 5 Disaggregating the three indicators provides a suggestion on the relative strengths and weaknesses in those areas. In terms of health status, Switzerland again ranks first, Austria 14th, and Mexico last. Regarding the non-medical factors, Sweden ranks first, and Austria 20th with Greece last. Finally, indicators of health outcomes surprisingly places Mexico first, Austria 11th and the United States the lowest.12 Similarly, the Social and Cultural Planning Office of the Netherlands compared health care in the EU plus Australia, Canada, New Zealand and the United States.13 They employ a range of indicators and group them into four indicators: 1) user charges, 2) waiting times, 3) public confidence in the system, and 4) health status, measured by life expectancy, quality-adjusted life years, infant mortality and self-assessed health. Through this exercise, the health systems in France, Sweden and Austria rank the highest since they score well in all four indices. A different way of measuring the performance of different countries’ health systems is by evaluating primary health care in terms of health outcomes.14 A study using OECD data found that strong primary care systems are negatively associated with aggregate and gender-specific mortality rates, overall levels of premature deaths, and premature deaths from asthma, heart disease, cerebrovascular disease and pneumonia, even when other determinants of health (e.g. GDP and behavioural factors) were controlled for. While lower mortality rates are associated with greater supply of primary care physicians, it seems that this is not the case with specialist physicians.15 Although the quest for a single number or ranking of performance is prioritised on policy makers’ agendas, it is highly unlikely that a single estimate could possibly capture the multitude of costs and benefits of the health system. Furthermore, a composite indicator compounds the inaccuracy of its component measures16. While rankings may be popular among policy makers, rankings based on a single measure may be misleading and uninformative, whereas rankings based on disaggregated indicators such as infant mortality, waiting lists or other specific measures are likely more easily related to policies or practices.17 Others have assessed health system performance along four key parameters: Health status, satisfaction and responsiveness, equity, and efficiency. This assessment was based on available quantitative data for countries that rely largely on social health insurance for funding.18 Health status is measured by life 12 Ibid. Social and Cultural Planning Office of the Netherlands, "Public Sector Performance," (The Hague: Social and Cultural Planning Office of the Netherlands, 2004). 14 J Macinko, B Starfield, and L Shi, "The Contribution of Primary Care Systems to Health Outcomes within Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) Countries, 1970-1998.," Health Systems Research 38, no. 3 (2003). 15 Barbara Starfield et al., "The Effects of Specialist Supply on Populations’ Health: Assessing the Evidence," Health Affairs Jan-Jun, no. Suppl Web Exclusives (2005). 16 C D Naylor, K Iron, and K Handa, "Measuring Health System Performance: Problems and Opportunities in the Era of Assessment and Accountability," in Measuring Up: Improving Health System Performance in OECD Countries, ed. P Smith (Paris: Organization for economic co-operation and development, 2002). 17 D Navarro, "Assessment of the World Health Report 2000," Lancet 356 (2000). 18 J Figueras et al., "Patterns and Performance in Social Health Insurance Systems," in Social Health Insurance Systems in Western Europe, ed. Richard B. Saltman, Reinhard Busse, and Josep Figueras (Copenhagen: World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2004). 13 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 14 expectancy, disability-adjusted life expectancy, and avoidable mortality. Satisfaction and responsiveness are measured through population, patient, and policy-makers’ surveys, in addition to examining the length of waiting times and levels of choice available in the health system. Equity of financing is measured through progressivity and regressivity estimates, as well as fairness of financial contribution estimates by the WHO. Finally efficiency is examined in four parts: cost and expenditure; relative resource levels and utilization rates; administration costs; and clinical performance (quality). The authors note that the complexity and often divergent organizational arrangements within the countries following the social health insurance model make evaluations incredibly difficult. It is important not to mistake health status with health care. In other words, we need to be cautious about drawing conclusions from measures of health system performance that are based, at least in part, on broad population health indicators. These measures of population health are largely affected by broader determinants such as social and educational policies, socio-economic and living conditions, inequalities, nutrition and other lifestyle factors. Moreover, some estimates suggest that health care might account for less than 20 percent of health improvement observed in the past century.19 1.1 Methodology This report provides a disaggregated approach to evaluate the performance of the Austrian health system from an international perspective. We do not attempt to calculate a composite indicator, but construct this evaluation on the basis of the different objectives and functions of the health system, building upon the evaluation frameworks developed by the WHO and OECD. The broad objectives can be categorised by the concepts of equity and efficiency. The various functions of the health system represent the means through which the objectives can be achieved: financing arrangement, payment methods, methods of resource allocation, delivery of care, quality of care, access to care, and to the extent that is possible, satisfaction. Finally, we present evidence on health status, in particular attempting to disentangle the impact of the health system on the health of the population. To summarise, the aim of this study was to evaluate the performance of the Austrian health system on the basis of the following criteria: - Distribution of costs and benefits across the population Access to care Regulation of the health system Allocative efficiency and resource allocation Technical efficiency Quality of care and patient satisfaction The contribution of the health system to health improvement Initially two reports were elaborated, one presenting the international evidence and experience with regards to performance measurement as well as presenting and analysing material for various countries related to the above mentioned criteria, the other describing and analysing the Austrian health care system, based on the above listed dimensions. In August 2006 the amalgamation of both reports was initiated and performed mostly by research staff at LSE Health and Social Care, The London School of Economics and Political Science. In addition to the joint report options for further research for Austria were elaborated, depicting either areas which require further research or showing gaps in data or resources encountered in the course of the project work. The methodology employed in the preparation of this report consisted of a combination of literature review, analysis of survey data, and interviews with Austrian stakeholders. 19 J Bunker, H Frazier, and F Mosteller, "Improving Health: Measuring Effects of Medical Care," Milbank Quarterly 72, no. 2 (1994). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 15 Empirical analysis of survey data was also undertaken. Several surveys were analysed: • • • • European Community Household Panel Survey Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe European Social Survey Eurobarometer Surveys The international report was developed by the London School of Economics and Political Science (led by Elias Mossialos and Sara Allin), and the Austrian report was written by Joy Ladurner. In the course of the project two co-operations were initiated for the Austrian part, one with Univ.-Prof. Dr. Anita Rieder (Prevention, measures of mortality amenable to medical intervention, factors contribution to changes in health status) and another with Mag. Daniel Hentschel MSc (Health expenditures, health indicators, factors affecting health status and health targets). Work on the Austrian part was initiated in October 2005. In addition to performing a comprehensive literature review, using databases such as Medline and Web of Knowledge as well as the internet search engine Google information (giving priority to national research reports and recent literature 2000-2006) resources were collected at various national institutions (ministries, social insurance, patient lawyer, etc.). For the literature review, electronic databases such as MEDLINE, EconLit, and JSTOR were searched. The Internet search engine Google was also used. Key terms that were used for searches included: • • • • • • • • • Health care + performance Health care + financing Health care + productivity Health care + efficiency Health care + access Health care + equity User charges Health care + patient choice Quality of care The sources identified in the searches were reviewed for relevance and the most up-to-date sources were selected. There were no restrictions on study design but preference was given to studies that were comparative across countries, and case studies reinforced by supporting observed or professionally provided evidence (from national authorities, purchasers and providers). Priority was given to national research reports and recent literature 2000-2006. Statistical data for Austria was compiled mostly based on sources from Statistik Austria, the Main organization of Austrian social insurance funds and the Austrian Medical Chamber. Furthermore numerous interviews with Austrian health care experts were conducted, representing the following institutions: - Main Organization of the Austrian Social Insurance Funds (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger) Social insurance funds Federal Ministry of Health Care and Women Patient lawyers (for the federal states of Lower Austria and Burgenland) Austrian Medical Chamber (Österreichische Ärztekammer), Academy of Doctors Austrian Federal Institute for Health Care (Österreichisches Bundesinstitut im Gesundheitswesen, ÖBIG) Institute of Advanced Studies (Institut für Höhere Studien, IHS) Universities A list of the interview partners can be found in Appendix 1. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 16 During the course of the project various meetings and presentations took place. A list of these, including names of participants, can be found in the Appendix 2. The report was produced both in German and in English. Translation of the Austrian part was done by Joy Ladurner, editing was undertaken by the London School of Economics and Political Science. Review of the Austrian section of this report20 for quality assurance was performed by Mag. Herta Marie Rack (Federal Ministry of Health and Women) and by Dr. Gottfried Endel (Main organization of the Austrian social insurance institutions). 20 Not including the appendices. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 17 2. DISTRIBUTION OF COSTS AND BENEFITS IN THE POPULATION 2.1 Funding health care Health care expenditure increased rapidly throughout the 1960s and early 1970s in the EU, and then reached a plateau.21 During the 1970s, a combination of economic recession following the 1974 oil crisis and the growing burden of unemployment eroded the view that increased welfare spending was sustainable. This change created a widespread belief that the welfare state was in crisis, yet these fears were not realized; in fact, welfare state spending has stabilized in many countries. However, health care expenditure has continued to rise. This situation may intensify the conflict between the demand for and the supply of public revenue for health care, unless countries pursue deficit financing,22 cut other areas of public expenditure, shift to private sources of revenue or increase efficiency.23 Despite the many methodological problems with international comparisons of health expenditure data, it appears that health care expenditure continued to grow throughout the 1980s and 1990s in most European countries (See Table 2.1). This was also the case with expenditure from public sources, especially in Ireland, Portugal and the United Kingdom, where public spending on health care has grown faster than total expenditure particularly since the mid- to late-1990s. Table 2.1 Percentage mean annual growth rates of total health expenditure (public health expenditure in parentheses) in the EU based on national currency units at 2000 GDP prices 1980-1985 1985-1990 1990-1995 1995-2000 2000-2004 (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) Austria -1.4 (0.6) 4.6 (3.9) 9.2 (7.9) 2.3 (2.5) 1.9 (2.2) Belgium 3.1 3.9 4.2 3.5 (2.8) Czech Republic 7.3 (5.8) 0.7 (0.6) 5.1 (4.7) Denmark 0.9 (0.4) 0.8 (0.2) 1.8 (1.7) 3.2 (3.2) 2.9 Finland 5.4 (5.3) 5 (5.6) -1.8 (-3.1) 2.3 (2.2) 5.5 (6) France 4.4 (4) 4.3 (3.8) 3.6 (3.6) 2.4 (2.2) 5.2 (6.1) Germany 2 (1.7) 2.1 (1.8) 8.4 (9.6) 2.3 (1.8) Greece 6.7 (6) 4.1 (4.3) 4.7 (4.7) Hungary 3 (-0.4) 8.3 (8.9) Ireland 0.6 (-0.9) 0.3 (-0.7) 6.9 (6.8) 8.1 (8.6) 8.7 (10.9) Italy -0.4 (-2.2) 4.1 (4.5) 2.4 (3.4) Luxembourg 2.3 (1.5) 8.2 (9.2) 4.8 (4.6) 7.2 (6.4) 11.6 (11.9) Netherlands 0.7 (1.1) 5.1 (4) 3.1 (4.3) 3.4 (1) 4.6 (4.3) Poland 4.8 (0.1) 5.4 (4.6) 6.4 (5.8) Portugal 2.6 6.1 (10.1) 7.5 (6.6) 6.7 (9.9) 2.2 (1.9) Slovak Republic Spain 1.6 (1.9) 8.7 (8.1) 4.2 (2.4) 3.4 (3.3) 6.1 (5.8) Sweden 0.9 (0.5) 1.9 (1.7) 0 (-0.7) 4 (3.6) 4.2 (4.3) United Kingdom 2.8 (2) 3.8 (3.2) 4.7 (4.8) 4.1 (3.3) 5.8 (7.3) Source: OECD Health data 2006 During the past decade, health care expenditure as a percentage of GDP appeared to grow more slowly, and even stabilized in some countries (See Table 2.2). GDP grew faster than health care expenditure between 21 22 H Glennerster, Paying for Welfare: Towards 2000. 3rd Ed. (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, 1997). Deficit financing is not a realistic option for the European Union countries that have joined the Economic and Monetary Union. 23 E Mossialos and A Dixon, eds., Funding Health Care: Options for Europe (Copenhagen: European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2002). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 18 1995 and 1998 in 8 of the 15 current EU countries, and in Denmark, Greece, Portugal and Spain, health care expenditure grew only slightly more than GDP.24 Thus, the stabilization of health care expenditure as a percentage of GDP in some EU countries may not reflect success in controlling growth in health care expenditure but rather economic growth. For example, the growth in health care expenditure in Ireland in the 1990s corresponded with economic growth of 8.8 per cent. In Finland and less notably in Sweden, health care expenditure actually declined. For Sweden, this decline actually reflects a shift in expenditure from health care budgets to social service budgets. In Finland, severe economic recession resulted in largescale cuts in expenditure, especially public expenditure. Although health care systems in the European Union are still characterised by a high degree of public expenditure, in some countries, there has been a decline in levels of public expenditure as a proportion of total health expenditure. Private expenditure grew substantially as a proportion of total expenditure on health care in Czech Republic, Portugal and the United Kingdom in the 1980s, and in Poland, Italy, Czech Republic, Luxembourg and Spain during the 1990s (Table 2.3). Health care expenditure continues to grow in the EU member states. Some explanations for this growth include: the ageing population, increases in labour costs, technological innovation, rising public expectations, and pressures from providers.25 There are also situational factors (e.g. political changes), structural changes (e.g. economic and demographic structure), changes in the labour market, the stability and capacity of political structures and institutions, environmental factors (e.g. changes in regulation, developments in science), and cultural factors (e.g. status of professionals and beliefs in government) that impact health care expenditure. Table 2.2 Total health care expenditure as a percentage of GDP in EU countries, 1980-2004 Austria Belgium Czech Republic Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Luxembourg Netherlands Poland Portugal Slovak Republic 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 7.5 6.5 7 9.7 9.4 9.5 9.5 9.6 9.6 6.3 7 7.2 8.2 8.6 8.7 8.9 10.1 4.7 7 6.7 7 7.2 7.5 7.3 8.9 6.3 7 8.7 6.6 8.5 7.1 7.9 9 8.3 7.5 5.2 7.2 5.2 7.1 5.6 6 8.3 7.8 8.4 8.5 7.4 6.1 7.7 5.4 7.7 4.9 6.2 8.1 7.4 9.4 10.3 9.6 7.4 6.7 7.1 5.6 8.1 5.6 8.2 8.3 6.7 9.2 10.4 9.9 7.1 6.3 7.9 5.8 7.9 5.7 9.4 5.5 8.6 6.9 9.3 10.6 10.4 7.3 6.8 8 6.4 8.3 6 9.3 5.5 8.8 7.2 10 10.8 10.3 7.7 7.2 8.2 6.8 8.9 6.6 9.5 5.6 8.9 7.4 10.4 10.9 10.5 8.3 7.2 8.2 7.7 9.1 6.5 9.8 5.9 8.9 7.5 10.5 10 8.3 7.1 8.4 8 9.2 6.5 10 24 The relationship between national income growth and health expenditure growth can be expressed as an expenditure elasticity. This is calculated as the change in total health care expenditure as a proportion of the change in GDP. Values greater than 1 indicate that growth in health care expenditure exceeds economic growth. 25 S. Altman and R. Blendon, eds., Medical Technology: The Culprit Behind Health Care Costs? (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1979), M.L. Barer, Evans, R.G., Hertzman, C., and Lomas, J., "Aging and Health Care Utilization: New Evidence on Old Fallacies," Social Science and Medicine 24 (1987), W. Baumol, "Health Care, Education and the Cost Disease: A Looming Crisis for Public Choice," Public Choice 77 (1993), K McGrail et al., "Age, Costs of Acute and Long-Term Care and Proximity to Death: Evidence for 1987-88 and 1994-95 in British Columbia," Age and Ageing 29 (2000), A.A. Scitovsky, " 'the High Cost of Dying': What Do the Data Show?," Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly 62, no. 4 (1984). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 19 Spain Sweden United Kingdom 5.3 9 5.6 5.4 8.6 5.9 6.5 8.3 6 7.4 8.1 7 7.2 8.4 7.3 7.2 8.7 7.5 7.3 9.1 7.7 7.9 9.3 7.9 8.1 9.1 8.3 Source: OECD Health data 2006 Table 2.4 disaggregates the two predominant private sources of funding – out-of-pocket payments and private insurance to observe trends over time. In general it appears that out-of-pocket payments has increased as a proportion of private health expenditure in many countries. On average, health systems financed largely through taxation spend more on health care than those relying on a model of social health insurance26. However, while the level of spending is higher in these countries, the recent growth rate has been equal (on a per capita basis) or lower than the countries with tax-funded systems. Also, the proportion of health spending that is public in the social health insurance countries tends to be lower than those funded through taxation ; and the overall public role in social health insurance funding decreased further in many countries in the 1990s (e.g. in the Netherlands). Table 2.3 Public and private expenditure as a percentage (%) of total health expenditure, 1980-2004 Austria Public Private Belgium Public Private Czech Rep. Public Private Denmark Public Private Finland Public Private France Public Private Germany Public Private Greece Public Private Hungary Public Private Ireland Public Private Italy Public Private Luxembourg Public Private Netherlands Public Private Poland Public Private Portugal Public Private 26 1980 68.8 31.2 1985 76.1 23.9 1990 73.5 26.5 96.8 3.2 87.8 12.2 79 21 80.1 19.9 78.7 21.3 55.6 44.4 92.2 7.8 85.6 14.4 78.6 21.4 78.5 21.5 77.4 22.6 97.4 2.6 82.7 17.3 80.9 19.1 76.6 23.4 76.2 23.8 53.7 46.3 81.6 18.4 75.7 24.3 92.8 7.2 69.4 30.7 89.2 10.8 70.8 29.2 64.3 35.7 54.6 45.4 71.9 28.1 79.1 20.9 93.1 6.9 67.1 32.9 91.7 8.3 65.5 34.5 1995 69.3 30.7 78.5 21.5 90.9 9.1 82.5 17.5 75.6 24.4 76.3 23.7 80.5 19.5 52 48 84 16 71.6 28.4 71.9 28.1 92.4 7.6 71 29 72.9 27.1 62.6 37.4 2000 69.9 30.1 75.8 24.2 90.5 9.5 82.4 17.6 75.1 24.9 75.8 24.2 78.6 21.4 52.6 47.4 70.7 29.3 73.3 26.7 73.5 26.5 89.3 10.7 63.1 36.9 70 30 72.5 27.5 2001 69.5 30.5 76.4 23.6 89.9 10.1 82.7 17.3 75.9 24.1 75.9 24.1 78.4 21.6 55.5 44.5 69 31 75.6 24.4 75.8 24.2 87.9 10 62.8 37.2 71.9 28.1 71.5 28.5 2002 70.5 29.5 75 25 89.7 10.3 82.9 17.1 76.1 23.9 78.1 21.9 78.6 21.4 54.1 45.9 70.2 29.8 75.2 24.8 75.4 24.6 90.3 9.7 62.5 37.5 71.2 28.8 72.2 27.8 2003 70.3 29.7 71.1 28.2 89.8 10.2 2004 70.7 29.3 76.2 23.8 78.3 21.7 78.2 21.8 53.6 46.4 72.4 27.6 78 22 75.1 24.9 90.6 9.4 63 36.9 69.9 30.1 72.6 27.4 76.6 23.4 78.4 21.6 89.2 10.8 52.8 47.2 72.5 27.5 79.5 20.5 76.4 23.6 90.4 9.6 62.3 37.6 68.6 31.4 71.9 28.1 Figueras et al., "Patterns and Performance in Social Health Insurance Systems." LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 20 Slovak Rep. Public Private Spain Public 79.9 Private 20.1 Sweden Public 92.5 Private 7.5 UK Public 89.4 Private 10.6 Source: OECD Health data 2006 81.1 18.9 90.4 9.6 85.8 14.2 78.7 21.3 89.9 10.1 83.6 16.4 72.2 27.8 86.6 13.4 83.9 16.1 89.4 10.6 71.6 28.4 84.9 15.1 80.9 19.1 89.3 10.7 71.2 28.8 84.9 15.1 83 17 89.1 10.9 71.3 28.7 85.1 14.9 83.4 16.6 88.3 11.7 70.4 29.6 85.4 14.6 85.4 14.6 70.9 29.1 84.9 15.1 85.5 14.5 Table 2.4 Out-of-pocket payments and voluntary health insurance as a proportion of private health expenditure, 1980-2003 1980 Austria Belgium Czech Rep. OOP VHI OOP VHI OOP VHI 24.4 1985 41 1990 1995 2000 2001 2002 34 49.7 30.7 55.3 28.8 51.5 28.4 50.9 29.8 100 100 100 100 92 8 81.8 10.3 43.3 52.5 49.7 38.6 95.2 4.8 89.3 1 48.8 26 83.9 3.7 64.7 9.3 23.4 43.6 100 Denmark OOP 93.1 94.6 92.6 93.3 91 VHI 6.9 5.4 7.4 6.7 9 Finland OOP 87.7 85.8 81.4 83.9 82 VHI 6.5 8.4 11.2 10 10.6 France OOP 64 66.9 48.7 45.5 43.4 VHI 28.5 27.5 46.9 50.3 52.2 Germany OOP 48.5 49.6 46.8 51.2 49.6 VHI 27.5 28.7 30.4 39.2 38.7 Greece OOP 94.7 VHI 5.3 Hungary OOP 100 89.8 VHI 0.6 Ireland OOP 59.5 58.7 54.7 50.5 VHI 32.5 31.9 28.4 Italy OOP 68.2 73.8 87.9 86.2 VHI 3 3.5 3.4 Luxembourg OOP 100 85.5 79.5 81.9 65.2 VHI 10 Netherlands OOP 24.3 VHI 43 Poland OOP 100 100 100 VHI Portugal OOP 80.8 VHI 0.5 2.3 3.5 11.1 Slovak Rep. OOP 100 VHI 0 0 Spain OOP 84.6 83.1 VHI 15.9 19.3 17.4 12.1 13.7 UK OOP 80.8 64.5 67.6 VHI 12.3 17.6 19.9 19.8 Note: OOP is out-of-pocket payments; VHI is voluntary health insurance Source: OECD 2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 81.3 11.3 100 2004 50.1 29.8 94.5 2.2 50.6 29.7 83.5 12 97.7 2.3 92.8 7.2 81.8 10.1 35.8 56.1 48.2 39.9 94.3 4.9 88.2 1.3 53 21.6 83.1 3.7 70.6 8.7 21.4 45.6 88.2 1.8 80.5 13.2 100 81.4 10.1 35.6 56.5 47.9 40.2 94.3 4.5 88.9 2.1 60.7 29 83.3 3.8 71.1 18.2 21.3 48.4 87.8 1.9 77.1 16.7 100 80.9 10 34.9 57.3 81.2 16 81 16.2 0 83.1 13.9 2003 95.5 2.1 95.7 4.3 88 3.2 65.9 32.7 83 4 69.9 17.6 20.8 50.7 89.5 1.9 76.8 17.4 0 82.6 14.3 21 2.1.2 Spending on health care in Austria Table 2.5 shows the change in total, public and private health care expenditure in Austria from 2000 to 2004. Nominal health care expenditure amounted to just over 22.8 billion Euros, 4.4% more than in 2003. Real growth (based on prices underlying the GDP in 2000) represented 2.9%. Public health care expenditure, situated at 16.1 billion Euros, amounted to 70.7% of total health care expenditure and increased by 5% from the previous year. Correspondingly, the level of private health care expenditure, which was 6.7 billion Euros in 2004, increased at a lower rate. Table 2.5 Spending on health care in Austria 2000 - 2004 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 215.900 220.700 227.000 237.000 2,61% 2,22% 2,85% 4,41% 212.300 214.100 216.800 223.000 % increase from previous year 0,90% 0,85% 1,26% 2,86% Health care expenditure, nominal, 19.786 million € % increase from previous year Health care expenditure, GDP 19.786 prices 2000, m. € % increase from previous year 20.559 21.057 21.802 22.770 3,91% 20.215 2,42% 20.424 3,54% 20.823 4,44% 21.417 2,17% 1,03% 1,95% 2,85% Public health care expenditure, 13.822 nominal, m. € % increase from previous year Private health care expenditure, 5.963 nominal, m. € % increase from previous year 14.287 14.853 15.330 16.091 3,36% 6.271 3,96% 6.204 3,21% 6.472 4,96% 6.679 5,17% -1,07% 4,32% 3,20% Total health care expenditure, as a 9,40% percentage of GDP 9,52% 9,54% 9,60% 9,61% Public expenditure, as a percentage 69,86% of total health expenditure 69,49% 70,54% 70,31% 70,67% as a 30,14% health 30,50% 29,46% 29,69% 29,33% 210.400 GDP, nominal, million € % increase from previous year GDP, GDP-prices 2000, million € Private expenditure, percentage of total expenditure 210.400 Note: Calculation method: OECD System of Health Accounts Source: Hofmarcher and Rack 2006 The above overview of expenditure on health care is based on the “System of Health Accounts” of the OECD, which was calculated for the first time in 2005 by Statistics Austria and published in February 2006. Past expenditure for 1995-2004 was assessed according to the same principles. The System of Health Accounts (SHA) calculates health care costs based on costing units, health care providers and types of benefits, thereby ensuring that all relevant expenditures are taken into consideration and facilitating LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 22 comparisons with data from other countries. In February 2002 14 OECD countries27 (out of these 7 EU countries) calculated their health care expenditure based on this calculation method28) Since the publication of a study by the Institute for Industrial Research (IWI)29 in 2002 (E. Pichler and E. Walter) on the funding of the Austrian health care system, the real level of Austrian health care expenditure has been subject to intense discussion. At the root of the debate is the definition of public health care expenditure, especially the expenditure on public hospitals. Further points of criticism are the classification of institutions for long-term care, rehabilitation and health promotion (health care resorts) as well as the consideration of financial long-term care benefits. Until 2004 health care expenditure was calculated according to the OECD/ ESA 95 (system of national accounts) which is compulsory in the EU. Based on this system of national accounts, which records expenditures in terms of consumption (who consumes how much?), public hospitals, whose expenses are covered to more than 50% by revenue, are classified as private producers in the market. This leads to a significant underestimation of actual health care expenditures, especially of public health care expenditure. Health care expenditure based on ESVG 95 amounts to 7.5% of the GDP whilst health care expenditure calculated according to the OECD System of Health Accounts reaches 9.6%. For details about the calculation of health care expenditure according to the OECD system of health accounts please see the webpage of Statistics Austria at http://www.statistik.at/fachbereich_03/gesundheit_ausgaben.shtml. Figure 2.1 displays total health care expenditure as a percentage of GDP in the different EU Member States. Austria now spends 9.6% of GDP on health care, according to the new SHA calculations, which places it above the EU 25 average of 8.6%. Within the EU, only Germany (10.9%) and France (9.7%) depict a higher health care quota. Figure 2.2 displays the share of public expenditure of total health care expenditure. When taking the EU 15 members as a basis, Austria, with a share of 70.7%, is situated in the lower third, with only Greece, Portugal and the Netherlands spending less from public sources. Figure 2.1Total health care expenditure as percentage of gross domestic product (GDP), last available year 6,5 EU10 since May EU (2003) EU15 before May Germany (2003) France (2003) Austria (2003) Greece (2003) Portugal (2003) Malta (2004) Sweden (2002) Belgium (2003) Netherlands (2003) Denmark (2003) Slovenia (2004) Italy (2003) Hungary (2002) United Kingdom Spain (2003) Ireland (2002) Finland (2003) Czech Republic Cyprus (2003) Luxembourg Poland (2002) Lithunia (2004) Slovakia (2003) Estonia (2004) Latvia (2003) 6,2 6,1 6,0 5,9 5,5 5,1 0,0 2,0 4,0 6,0 8,6 9,0 7,8 7,7 7,6 7,3 7,3 7,1 7,0 8,0 9,7 9,6 9,5 9,3 9,2 9,2 9,1 8,8 8,8 8,6 8,5 10,0 10,9 12,0 Source: Hofmarcher and Rack (2006); WHO Health for All Database. (updated: January 2006, accessed 10/05/2006) 27 OECD countries: Switzerland, Turkey, Japan, Canada, Korea, Mexiko. OECD and EU countries: Denmark, Germany, Netherlands, Poland, Spain, Hungary, Austria 28 Institute of Advanced Studies (Institut für Höhere Studien, IHS). “New calculation of health care expenditure lets Austria appear in the correct light.″ Press information. 21 February 2006. Vienna. 29 Institute for Industrial Research (Industriewissenschaftliches Institut, IWI) LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 23 Figure 2.2 Public health care expenditure as a percentage of total health expenditure, last available year Czech Republic (2004) Slovakia (2003) Luxembourg (2002) Sweden (2002) United Kingdom (2002) Denmark (2003) Slovenia (2004) Germany (2003) Italy (2004) Estonia (2003) France (2003) Finland (2003) Ireland (2002) Lithunia (2004) Poland (2002) Malta (2004) Spain (2003) Belgium (2003) Austria (2003) Portugal (2003) Hungary (2002) Netherlands (2003) Latvia (2004) Greece (2003) Cyprus (2003) 91.2 89.4 85.4 85.3 83.4 83.0 79.0 78.5 76.4 76.3 76.0 75.7 75.2 72.6 72.4 71.8 71.3 71.2 70.7 70.5 70.2 65.6 64.1 52.9 41.3 0.0 20.0 40.0 60.0 80.0 100.0 Sources: Hofmarcher and Rack 2006; WHO Health for All Database (updated: January 2006, accessed 10/05/2006) 2.2 Sources of funding European health care systems rely on a mix of funding sources with the majority providing universal (or near universal) statutory health coverage. Most funding is public expenditure from taxation (as in Denmark, Finland, Italy, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and the United Kingdom), social health insurance (as in Austria, France, Germany, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands), or a combination of both (as seen in Belgium and Greece). Taxation Taxation has different sources (direct or indirect), different levels (national or local) and different types (general or hypothecated), each with varying implications for equity and efficiency. Direct taxes, which predominantly fund health care in the UK, are taxes levied on individuals, households or firms. Direct taxes have the potential to redistribute income between rich and poor people. For example, personal income taxes, a form of direct tax, are progressive if tax rates are higher for those with higher incomes. However, horizontal inequities occur in situations where income tax rates vary geographically, some forms of income are exempt from income tax, or some forms of expenditure are tax-deductible.30 Indirect taxes, taxes on 30 E Van Doorslaer et al., "The Redistributive Effect of Health Care Finance in Twelve OECD Countries," Journal of Health Economics 18, no. 3 (1999). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 24 transactions and commodities, are more regressive than direct taxes as they relate to consumption and not income.31 Taxes may be collected locally, as in Denmark, Finland, Norway, Sweden and Italy, or nationally, as in Greece, Portugal, Spain and the UK. There are several arguments in favour of local versus national taxation. First, there is increased transparency since there is a closer link between the amount generated and the amount spent on health care. Second, there is more accountability because local politicians are closer to the electorate and allocation decisions are more apparent. Third, there is more responsiveness to local performance. Fourth, health is separated from competing national priorities. However, there are some disadvantages associated with local taxation. For instance, inequities can arise if tax rates vary across regions, or if the same tax rate yields differing revenue according to the wealth of different regions. On the other hand, national taxation has several potential advantages. First, this method has the potential to redistribute across the whole of the income distribution within a country. Second, it allows trade-offs to be made between health and other sectors. Third, collecting taxes nationally benefits from administrative economies of scale.32 However, there are trade-offs with other spending or transfer programs, tax or debt reduction. Taxation may be general, as in Italy, or hypothecated (earmarked for health care), as in France. General taxation draws on a broad revenue base and allows trade-offs between health care and other sectors, however allocation to health care is subject to public spending negotiations which may or may not be favourable. On the other hand, hypothecated taxes may reduce resistance to taxation because it is more visible33, it increases transparency and responsiveness34 and they may be less susceptible to political manipulation. However, hypothecated taxation may cause increased rigidity in the budgetary process, and prevent integrated public health policies.35 Social health insurance Social health insurance provides the organizing principle and much of the funding in seven Western European countries: Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, and Switzerland.36 Social health insurance is essentially an earmarked payroll tax that usually relies on contributions that are shared between the employer and the employee. The advantages of the social health insurance model are common to those associated with hypothecated taxation. For instance, it is more transparent than taxation hence more acceptable to the public in general. Also, social health insurance revenue may be better protected from political interference than revenue from taxation since an independent system of revenue collection is at an arm’s length from government.37 However there are some disadvantages associated with this method of financing. For example, since employers are often required to pay large contributions, labour costs may rise, resulting in negative economic implications. Also, if eligibility to health insurance is dependent on income or employment, there may be limited access to health care for the not employed population. 31 J Hills, "Taxation for the Enabling State," in CASE Discussion Paper No. 41 (London: Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, London School of Economics and Political Science, 2000). 32 Mossialos and Dixon, eds., Funding Health Care: Options for Europe. 33 Commission on Taxation and Citizenship, "Paying for Progress: A New Politics of Tax for Public Spending," (London: Fabian Society, 2000). 34 A Jones and A Duncan, Hypothecated Taxation: An Evaluation of Recent Proposals (London: Office of Health Economics, 1995). 35 E Mossialos, A Dixon, and M McKee, "Paying for the NHS," BMJ 320 (2000). 36 R.B Saltman, "Social Health Insurance in Perspective: The Challenge of Sustaining Stability," in Social Health Insurance Systems in Western Europe, ed. R.B Saltman, R Busse, and J Figueras (Copenhagen: World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2004). 37 Mossialos and Dixon, eds., Funding Health Care: Options for Europe. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 25 The types of collection agents vary: France has devolved independent funds, Belgium, Germany and the Netherlands have individual health insurance funds with open enrolment, Greece has individual health insurance funds organized by occupational groups, and Luxembourg has an association of insurance funds. The different organizational arrangements have their advantages and disadvantages. For instance, multiple funds may compete which may, in turn, improve efficiency, however a single fund may have lower administrative costs because of the monopsony purchaser and a universal risk pool, which is more desirable from an equity perspective. Voluntary health insurance The majority of health care spending derives from public sources in the EU, however, the last twenty years have seen a shift from public to private expenditure. The main sources of private funding for health care include voluntary health insurance (VHI) and out-of-pocket payments. The agents collecting VHI premiums can be independent, private-for-profit insurance companies (in countries that have a VHI market) or private not-for-profit insurance companies and funds (in Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Spain and the UK).38 VHI can be classified as substitutive, supplementary or complementary.39 Substitutive insurance substitutes cover otherwise available from the state. Substitutive insurance is available in Germany and the Netherlands for individuals with high incomes who wish to opt out of (or, as in the case of the Netherlands, are excluded from) statutory insurance scheme. Portugal and Italy’s proposals to permit people to opt out of the public system were withdrawn in response to considerable resistance. Supplementary insurance provides cover for faster access and increased consumer choice. Because supplementary insurance allows individuals additional or higher quality services than what is offered through the public system, differential access between those with and without this insurance may result. Complementary insurance provides cover for services excluded or not fully covered by the state, including cover for co-payments for public services. Tax incentives to purchase VHI exist in most European countries, although recently there have been some efforts to reduce or remove tax incentives in some countries as they are argued to be expensive, regressive (i.e. benefits higher income earners disproportionately), and largely unsuccessful in stimulating demand40. There are no tax incentives for individuals to purchase any kind of VHI in Denmark, Finland, Spain or the United Kingdom, and there are no tax benefits for employers purchasing VHI for their employees in Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Sweden or the United Kingdom. In Austria, Ireland and Portugal, private health insurance is partly subsidised by the state using tax credits or tax relief. In Austria, there are tax incentives for individuals as well as firms, although they have been reduced significantly in recent years. Single people can deduct 25% of VHI premiums from taxable income, up to a limit of €2,907, provided their gross income does not exceed €36,336.41 Firms can deduct all premiums paid for their employers from tax. Spending on VHI as a proportion of private expenditure is relatively low, accounting for less than 5 per cent in Greece, Italy and Portugal and around 25 per cent in Austria, Spain and the United Kingdom. Spending on VHI constitutes a much higher proportion of private expenditure in Germany (29.9 per cent), where higher income groups are able to opt out of the statutory system, and the Netherlands (70 per cent), in the form of substitutive insurance, where individuals over an income threshold are required to leave the statutory system, and France (51.7 per cent), where there is extensive coverage of co-payments.42 38 Ibid. (Mossialos and Thomson 2004) 40 E Mossialos and S Thomson, Voluntary Health Insurance in the European Union (Copenhagen: World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2004). 41 Ibid. 42 Ibid. 39 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 26 In Austria, about one third of the population subscribed to VHI in 1998 with 18.8% holding complementary VHI and 12.9% supplementary.43 But the share of total health spending from VHI is low. The proportion is quite high because of Austrians’ propensity to purchase complementary VHI to cover hospital per diem charges. Supplementary VHI in Austria covers physician costs, supplementary hospital costs, and offers faster access and increased choice. Subscribers to VHI in Austria tend to be mostly high income earners. About half of those with VHI are self-employed, and about 40% are civil servants or salaried employees. There are different levels of uptake across the country, with individuals residing in Carinthia most likely to purchase VHI. Cost sharing Out-of-pocket payments comprise a substantial proportion of private health care expenditure in many European countries, especially in Austria, Finland, Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain and the Netherlands44 (as shown in Table 2.4). The highest proportion of financing through out-of-pocket payments is in Greece, which resultantly has a highly regressive system of financing. Among European governments user charges are generally preferred to promoting and subsidising VHI. Advocates of user charges argue that they discourage excess utilization of health services by creating price signals which deter individuals from consuming unnecessary care45. Hence, cost sharing is argued to improve efficiency at a micro level while containing costs at macro level. In countries where public budgets are under pressure, cost sharing has been argued to be one mechanism for generating revenue. However, many argue against user charges stating that information asymmetries in health care present a major obstacle to achieving any gains in efficiency, since individuals are not always able to differentiate necessary from unnecessary services. Furthermore, health care spending is primarily driven by supply side factors therefore cost containment in the long-term is unlikely to result from a cost sharing arrangement. Finally, it is widely agreed that user charges have undesirable effects on equity in two ways: by shifting the financial burden onto the individual; and introducing barriers to access for individuals on low income. Out-of-pocket payments can come in broadly three forms: direct payments (‘pure private’ payments), cost sharing (individuals who are covered pay part of the costs of care received) and informal payments (unofficial payments for services that should be fully funded by the public system). Cost sharing exists to some extent in all European health systems. The three forms of direct cost sharing consist of: co-payment, where the user pays a fixed (flat) fee per item or service; co-insurance, which refers to the user paying a fixed proportion of the total cost; and deductible, wherein the user bears a fixed quantity of the costs. Among the original 15 EU Member States, cost-sharing is applied to pharmaceuticals and dental care in all countries. For GP, specialist and hospital care, however, only Austria46, Belgium, Finland, France, Ireland (Category II patients47), Luxembourg and Sweden impose cost-sharing. In Germany and Portugal, physician services are free at the point of use but cost sharing is applied to inpatient care.48 43 Ibid. In 1999 85 per cent of the French population was covered by complementary VHI to cover the cost of statutory copayments, while 28.9 per cent of the Dutch population is excluded from statutory coverage of primary care and acute inpatient care. 45 B. Abel-Smith, An Introduction to Health: Policy, Planning and Financing (London: Longman, 1994), M Chalkley and R Robinson, Theory and Evidence on Cost Sharing in Health Care: An Economic Perspective (London: Office of Health Economics, 1997), J. Kutzin, "The Appropriate Role for Patient Cost Sharing. Critical Challenges for Health Care Reform in Europe," ed. R.B Saltman, J Figueras, and C Sakellarides (Buckingham: Open University Press, 1998). 46 Some sickness funds 44 47 48 Category II patients in Ireland are those with higher incomes. S Thomson, E Mossialos, and N Jemiai, "Cost Sharing for Health Services in the European Union," (Brussels: European Commission DG Employment and Social Affairs, 2003). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 27 GP and ambulatory specialist cost sharing tends to be in the form of co-payments or co-insurance. For inpatient care, cost sharing tends to be in the form of a co-payment per day ranging from about €5-10 in Austria49, France, Germany and Luxembourg, to €26-65 in Finland, Ireland (Category II patients) and Belgium. Prescription drugs may have cost sharing in the form of a fixed co-payment as in Austria (€4.25) and the United Kingdom (€8.80) whereas a fixed deductible is combined with co-insurance in the remaining countries. However in Sweden individuals must pay the full cost of prescription drugs up to an out-ofpocket maximum. Protection mechanisms are in place in all countries in order to protect lower income earners from the financial burden of cost sharing arrangements. Protection mechanisms for inpatient care user charges tend to be annual out-of-pocket maximums ranging from about €100 in Sweden to about €600 in Finland.50 Exemptions can also be granted for very long hospital stays, for example inpatient stays longer than 14 days in Germany or 28 days in Austria. For pharmaceuticals, significant population groups are exempt from cost sharing in many countries. For instance, individuals with low incomes are exempt in Austria, Belgium, Germany, Ireland and United Kingdom, and older people in Greece. In addition, exemptions may be targeted towards individuals with a clinical condition, e.g. diabetes in Sweden, pregnancy in the United Kingdom, or certain age groups such as children in Germany and the United Kingdom, and older people in Belgium, Ireland, Spain and the United Kingdom51. Certain types of drugs may be exempt from cost sharing, e.g. for chronic illnesses in Portugal, for life-threatening illnesses in Belgium, both types of drugs in Germany, and effective drugs in France. Also, out-of-pocket maximums for pharmaceutical costs exist in Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Ireland, Italy and Sweden. Funding reforms Systems of financing are not static; rather the contributions to total health spending of the different sources of funding have changed over time in some countries. In France, for instance, in 1998, “general social contributions” (CSG) were introduced such that social insurance contributions were based on total income rather than salary alone. Since then, employees’ contributions have fallen from 6.8 to 0.75% of gross earnings. This change thus represented a shift from a social insurance model based on wage to a more tax-financed model based on total income. Debates about reforming the financing system in Germany are ongoing. Similar to France, it has been argued that the payroll taxes should draw from a wider tax base than solely gross salary. Despite the extensive discussions taking place and repeated calls to shift funding towards taxation, the German Government is still yet to decide whether to make any reforms to the financing system. 2.2.1 Sources of funding in Austria Table 2.6 shows the corresponding shares from the different sources of funding out of total health care expenditure. About 45% of Austrian expenditure on health care is funded by social insurance. Contributions, which are income-dependent (on average between 7.1% and 9.1% of the contribution base) are collected by the sickness funds and are mainly used for reimbursement of benefits in the primary and tertiary sector (excluding long-term care).52 49 User charges for inpatient care are based on regional hospital law and on social insurance law (may be both) N Jemiai, S Thomson, and E Mossialos, "An Overview of Cost Sharing for Health Services in the European Union," Euro Observer 2004. 51 Thomson, Mossialos, and Jemiai, "Cost Sharing for Health Services in the European Union." 52 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 50 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 28 Table 2.6 Share of total health expenditure from different sources (in % of total expenditure) Sources of funding, in % of 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 health expenditure Public 67.8 67.6 67.8 67.8 69.1 70.1 70.0 70.4 Taxes 22.5 23.3 22.4 22.3 23.8 24.3 24.7 25.1 - for long-term care 8.7 8.4 8.4 8.3 8.2 8.1 8.0 7.7 Social health insurance 45.3 44.4 45.4 45.6 45.3 45.8 45.3 45.3 Private 26.3 26.8 26.4 26.8 25.9 25.4 25.4 25.0 Private health insurance 3.3 3.9 3.7 3.9 2.82 2.3 2.3 2.4 b Indirect user charges 14.7 14.5 14.1 14.1 13.8 13.7 13.6 13.5 Direct user chargesc 6.8 6.9 7.1 7.3 7.7 7.7 7.9 7.6 Private non-profit 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.4 organizationsd Employerse 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 f Investments 5.9 5.5 5.7 5.3 5.0 4.6 4.6 4.6 a Total health expenditure 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 a) OECD System of Health Accounts b) Defined as user charges of households not covered by social insurance by private households, including services of private insurance in the inpatient sector c) Defined as user charges of private households to services provided by social health insurance d) Expenditure of private, non-profit hospitals, emergency ambulance services as well as expenditures for others, services provided by private non-profit organizations e) Services provided by company physicians f) Including public and private investments (private investments also include the investments of the hospital associations) Source: Hofmarcher and Rack (2006) About 20% of health care expenditure is funded by taxes, primarily by general taxes and value added tax, and is in the first instance used to pay for inpatient care in hospitals but also for public health services (Öffentlicher Gesundheitsdienst). The federal states (Länder) are the owners of public hospitals, therefore they are responsible for covering the investment- and maintenance costs, as well as running costs.53 The share of health care expenditure funded by taxes has increased since 1997.54 The legal representatives of university hospitals receive a lump sum from central government to cover “additional clinical expenses55” for training and research. Financial means for construction work and investments are also negotiated between central government and the legal representatives of the hospitals. Funds generated by tobacco tax are partially shifted to the Healthy Austria Fund (Fonds Gesundes Österreich), which is engaged in health prevention matters, and also to the equalization fund of the Austrian statutory sickness funds. Private households contribute about 29% of total health care expenditure in terms of direct and indirect user charges and private insurance. In 2004 Austria had the 3rd highest proportion of private funding in the EU15 countries and the 9th highest among 30 OECD countries56. Between 1995 and 2002 private health care expenditure increased by 45%57, but as a percentage of total health spending, it declined between 1997 and 2005 (Table 2.6). 53 running costs Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 55 additional clinical expenses (klinischer Mehraufwand) 56 OECD health data, accessed 01/09/2006 57 Hofmarcher, M., Riedel, M., Röhrling, G. (2004), ″Focus: Health remains precious to us–so what?.″ Health System Watch I:2004, supplement of the journal of Social insurance in Austria, Soziale Sicherheit. 54 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 29 Table 2.7 shows the composition of private health care expenditure. In the year 2004, 57.6% of private expenditure consisted of indirect user charges (cost sharing) for benefits/services or products not included in the reimbursement scheme of the sickness funds. Examples of services with cost sharing arrangements include inpatient care (52.8%58), dental services (29.8%) and pharmaceutical products (12.4% of total indirect user charges). 32.3% of private health care expenditure are direct co-payments, being either fixed charges or other co- payments (e.g. prescription charge). Furthermore costs arise due to the partial reimbursement of benefits when using non-contract doctors. The remaining 10.1% of total private health expenditure derive from private health insurance. Table 2.7 Composition of private health care expenditure Indirect Direct user charges user charges Private health insurance 59.1% 57.2% 56.6% 55.7% 56.8% 57.8% 57.0% 57.6% 13.4% 15.5% 15.0% 15.3% 11.5% 9.8% 9.7% 10.1% 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 27.4% 27.3% 28.5% 28.9% 31.7% 32.4% 33.3% 32.3% Source: Adapted from Hofmarcher and Rack 2006. The share of voluntary private health insurance amounts to 2.4%59 (see Table 2.6) of total health care expenditures. The reason it is such a small proportion could be the comprehensive coverage provided by statutory social health insurance. Private health insurance in Austria is mainly used to pay for better accommodation in the private ward of hospitals, treatment by a certain doctor60 and reductions in waiting time. However, private health insurance accounts for 7%61 of the public hospital revenue. 2.3 Defining benefits and beneficiaries In recent decades there has been a trend towards extending coverage to health services. Indeed, Table 2.8 shows that all OECD countries cover 100% or almost 100% of the population to statutory health insurance. At the same time there has been an increase in user charges in some countries in recent years, which has eroded coverage to some extent. The only countries that have not achieved universal coverage of the population are Germany and the Netherlands (which offers or compels individuals over a certain income threshold to take up private insurance instead of the statutory insurance) and the United States. 58 Hospitals, spas, nursing homes Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 60 The doctor is either employed in the hospital (and receives a share of the payment from the private health insurance company) or the doctor is a private and has an arrangement with the private hospital to come and operate using their facilities. 61 ibid 59 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 30 Table 2.8 Proportion of the population covered by statutory health insurance 1970 1980 1990 2000 2004 Australia Austria Belgium Canada Czech Republic Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Iceland Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom United States 85 91 97.8 100 100 100 100 95.6 89.2 55 100 85 93 100 100 100 40 61 100 89 100 100 99 99 100 100 100 100 99.1 92.3 88 100 100 100 100 100 74.6 100 100 100 83 100 96.5 100 100 99 97.3 100 100 100 100 99.4 88.8 100 100 100 100 100 100 73.9 100 100 100 98.1 100 99.5 100 24.5 100 99 99 100 100 100 100 99.9 90.9 100 100 100 100 100 100 77.6 100 100 100 98.9 100 100 100 24.7 100 98 99 100 100 100 100 99.9 89.8 100 100 100 100 100 76.3 100 100 100 100 100 100 Source: OECD Health data 2006 In many European countries, there is a legal basis for entitlement to health care services. Among the countries with social health insurance systems, Germany legislates that all insured citizens are entitled to receive all ‘reasonable and effective’ health services necessary for the treatment of diseases. Services and technologies should be ‘medically necessary, effective and cost-effective.62 Most other countries indicate the importance of medical necessity and effectiveness, however not all countries consider economic aspects as important. Table 2.9 provides a brief description of the basis for defining the benefits package in some social health insurance systems. Benefits packages are an essential part of social health insurance systems; they not only clarify the entitlements to health care for citizens, but also facilitate reimbursement for providers and control the diffusion of new technologies. However several factors in recent years have been putting pressure on decision-makers to place limits on the broad frame of social health insurance systems. Among others, these factors include rising demand by patients coupled with supplier-induced demand, the ‘medicalization’ of society, and rising health care costs63. While there is growing discussion about the possibility of restricting the benefits packages in social health insurance countries to only the core basic, medically necessary services, so far no country has been able to do so. Countries have responded by making use of two types of regulations that may be implicit, such as negative lists, or explicit, such as positive lists to define benefits packages. 62 B Gibis, P.W. Koch-Wulkan, and J. Bultman, "Shifting Criteria for Benefit Decisions in Social Health Insurance Systems," in Social Health Insurance Systems in Western Europe, ed. R.B Saltman, R Busse, and J Figueras (Copenhagen: World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2004). 63 Ibid. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 31 Most countries rely on a combination of positive lists (e.g. benefits catalogues) and negative lists for the different sectors. For instance, in ambulatory care, of the seven countries listed in Table 2.9, all make use of explicit regulation, i.e. a benefits catalogue or positive list (in the case of Austria, the list is not closed, rather additional benefits are possible on an individual basis) with the exception of the Netherlands (which uses a negative list for specialist care) and Switzerland (no regulation). For inpatient care, Austria, Belgium and Luxembourg rely on explicit regulation of the benefits package, in Netherlands they also use negative list, and there is no regulation in France, Germany and Switzerland64. All countries explicitly regulate medical devices, and all but Germany (implicit) do so for pharmaceuticals. Decisions regarding benefit catalogues can only formally be challenged in some countries, such as for pharmaceuticals in Austria and Switzerland, and for other services in ‘social courts’ in Austria and Germany, or civil courts in Belgium and the Netherlands.65 Unlike social health insurance and private health insurance systems, coverage through many national health service-type systems is not based on a defined list of benefits. For instance, in the UK, under the National Health Service Act 1977, the Secretary of State for Health has a duty to provide a health service ‘to such an extent as he considers necessary to meet all reasonable requirements’. A detailed discussion on health technology assessment, a tool used to determine which medical technologies or pharmaceuticals will be reimbursed, is provided in section 5.1. Table 2.9 Legal framework for accepting services and technologies to the benefit package Country Terms Legal base Austria Medically necessary, sufficient, General Social Insurance Act (ASVG) appropriate §133(2) Belgium Medical necessity, activity, cost- Published by Royal Decree effectiveness, safety France Inscription of new medical and Decree to be published soon surgical procedures after advice of ANAES on efficacy and safety Germany Medically necessary, effective, cost- Social Code Book (SGB) V, §135(1) effective Luxembourg 1. Sufficient, appropriate 1. Code des assurances socials, art. 2. Medically necessary, effective, 17.1 efficient 2. Code des assurances socials, art. 23.1 The Netherlands Medically necessary Sickness Fund Act (ZFW), preamble Switzerland Effective, appropriate, cost-efficient Swiss Insurance Law (KVG), §32 Source: Gibis, Koch-Wulkan et al 2004 2.3.1 Defining benefits in the Austrian health system (what is covered?)66 Service coverage of the legal health insurance is legislated in the social insurance laws (ASVG, B-KUVG, GSVG, BSVG and FSVG67). Health insurance funds retain only limited scope. Services can be classified in respect of their legal nature (compulsory services, voluntary services or compulsory duties) or by the way in 64 Ibid. Ibid. 66 Section 5.1.1 provides more detailed description of the health technology assessment process in Austria. 67 ASVG=Allgemeines Sozialversicherungsgesetz (General Social Insurance Law), B-KUVG=Beamten Kranken- und Unfallversicherungsgesetz (Civil Servants’ Health- and Accident Insurance Law), GSVG=Gewerbliches Sozialversicherungsgesetz (Commercial Social Inusrance Law, for self employed), BSVG=Bauern Sozialversicherungsgesetz (Farmers’ Social Insurance Law), FSVG= Bundesgesetz über die Sozialversicherung freiberuflich selbständig Erwerbstätiger (Federal law regarding social insurance for freelance, self employed persons) 65 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 32 which they are provided (allowance in kind or cash benefits).68 The insured person (on submission of an insurance case as well as fulfilment of certain criteria69) has an enforceable right to compulsory benefits (e.g. treatment of illness). With the compulsory services, differentiation must be made between the minimum legal service requirements (type, scope, and conditions are governed by law) and the statutory additional services (health insurance funds are permitted to define more comprehensive services in their statutes (according to grounds, level, or duration), as long as these remain within the scope of the model statutes set out by the Hauptverband). The insured person has no enforceable legal claim to preventive services (measures to improve health, e.g. stays in convalescent homes or services related to health promotion), these are granted at the discretion of the health insurance fund. The insured person has no individual legal claim to compulsory duties (e.g. medical rehabilitation or health promotion), these are to be provided at the dutiful discretion of the insurance fund. Differences in the package of services provided by different insurance funds can occur due to various reasons: - Variations in legal regulations, e.g. when utilising inpatient care in the private ward, special services are available for B-KUVG (civil servants) insured and GSVG insured70 (self-employed). - Variations in contractual rules.71 (Insurance funds have varying contractual arrangements with providers of health care services. These variations can not be entirely explained by the individual sickness fund but are also dependent on the contract partner, i.e. the representative association) - The financial situation of the sickness fund, for instance the regional fund in Vienna does not reimburse Spa treatment - Variations in the levels of co-payments set by the sickness funds - Variations between branches of sickness funds, e.g. in health insurance (sufficient and appropriate, not exceeding the necessary amount) and in accident insurance (with all appropriate means) and also depend on the insured event (illness vs. occupational illness). Services are provided either as allowance in kind (in form of tangible assets or provision of service) or as cash benefits. The first can be called upon by contractual partners (contractual facilities, contract doctors) or the insurance funds’ own facilities. The latter may be claimed once or repeatedly (ongoing). The health insurance primarily provides benefits in kind72, cash benefits predominate in accident and pension insurance.73 There are variations in the terms for persons entitled to cash benefit insured by the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (Sozialversicherungsanstalt der gewerblichen Wirtschaft, SVA). Cash-benefits provided in health insurance are partially calculated based on the income of the insured. This applies to benefits such as sickness allowance (Krankengeld) which is supposed to be a substitute for income during a spell of sickness, daily allowance (Taggeld) according to the GSVG, maternity benefit (Wochengeld) or business allowance/maternity benefit (Betriebshilfe/Wochengeld) according to the GSVG/BSVG. Cash benefits which are independent of the income of the insured include child care benefit74, the additional subsidy to the child care benefit75 or other allowances in the context of rehabilitation, e.g. for adaptation of an apartment or a car. 68 § 121 ASVG Seidl, W. (2002), Social Insurance Law. Skriptum, Graz, Neuer Wissenschaftlicher Verlag. Reiter, G. (2002). ″Compulsory insurance versus the obligation to take out insurance – more than a play of words?″ WISO 3, pp. 79-90. 70 Those consuming benefits in cash; they have an option whereby they can opt to pay higher contributions for hospital care meaning that they are treated in the private ward instead of general ward. 71 Schrammel, W. (2002). Report of the chair of the expert commission „Compulsory insurance – the obligation to take out insurance“, accessible at http://www.auva.at/mediaDB/63990.PDF#search=%22Schramml%20Expertenkommission%20Pflichtversicherun g%22. 72 Federal Ministry of Social Insurance, Generations and Consumer Protection, BMSGK (2003). Social protection in Austria, an overview, Vienna. Kind, M. (2005). My rights as a patient. Vienna, Verlag des Österreichischen Gewerkschaftsbundes GmbH. 73 Seidl, W. (2002), Social Insurance Law. Skriptum, Graz, Neuer Wissenschaftlicher Verlag. 74 a yearly threshold for additional earnings of € 14,600 exists 75 In certain cases income-dependent 69 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 33 The service commitment or scope is based, in part, on the recommendations of the supreme sanitary council (definition of what is the medical standard?) and diverse internal expert committees of the insurance funds. The final decision lies with the political decision makers76. The definition of disease treatment in accordance with § 133 ASVG para.1 has a considerable influence on the scope of services provided by the health insurance, according to which disease treatment should be “adequate and appropriate, it must however not exceed the level of what is necessary”. Treatment is dependent on the curative understanding of the definition of illness (§ 120 ASVG para. 1 1.), which is defined as “an irregular state of body or mind making treatment necessary”. Regarding the definition of “illness” it is important to note that different understandings exist, as the current definition stated in the law gives room to subjective perceptions and thus different methods of interpretation. Due to this reason the case may occur in which a sickness fund is obliged to reimburse a certain benefit even if it is not part of the benefits package. Decisions regarding these issues are taken by the senior physician of the fund or, in case the insured addresses court, by the respective institution. 2.3.2 Defining beneficiaries in the Austrian health system (who is covered?) In Austria social insurance is governed by law77 and is based on the principle of compulsory insurance. It encompasses the branches of health insurance, accident insurance and pension insurance as well as, unemployment insurance.78 In 2005 97.8% of the population (about 8.2 million) were covered by social health insurance79. Individuals become insured after starting a job, by fulfilling other compulsory insurance criteria (compulsory insurance) or by way of a derivative insurance cover (e.g. joint-insured dependants). For those without compulsory insurance there is the possibility of voluntary insurance. Affiliation to a social insurance fund cannot, apart from a few exceptions, be freely chosen by the insured person (see Section 7.3.1 on “Patient choice in Austria”). Health insurance funds are classified by occupational groups and, in the case of general employed persons, also by region. With salaried employees (ASVG) the health insurance fund is notified by the employer, self-employed (SVA, SVB) and voluntarily insured individuals register themselves, pensioners are registered through the respective pension insurance fund and the unemployed via the Public Employment Service Austria (AMS). As already mentioned, the dependants of gainfully employed individuals e.g. husband/wife, children (mostly free of charge) may be joint-insured as long as they are residing within the country80 and do not have their own health insurance. In 2005 this group of people constituted around 26% of all insured persons.81 Protection of insured with low or no income Low wage employees, so called “minimum wage” employees82, are upon commencement of employment, solely covered by accident insurance, they may however, voluntarily obtain health and pension insurance for a comparatively low monthly fee (€47.0183) (§ 19a ASVG). On the 1st July 2004, 42,024 persons took advantage of this option.84 Foreign nationals working in Austria are covered by the legal health insurance through their employer or possibly as relatives, unemployed or pensioners. Should they not fit into one of 76 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 77 General Social Insurance Law (ASVG), Special Laws (Sondergesetze): GSVG (Gewerbliches Sozialversicherungsgesetz), B-KUVG (Kranken- und Unfallversicherungsgesetz der Beamten), BSVG (Bauern Sozialversicherungsgesetz), FSVG (Sozialversicherungsgesetz der Freiberuflich Selbständigen Erwerbstätigen) as well as relevant amendments 78 Unemployment insurance is organised by the Public Employment Service Austria (Arbeitsmarktservice, AMS) and is independent 79 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, incl. individuals insured with health care institutions (Krankenfürsorgeanstalten) 80 Exception: stay abroad for study purposes 81 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (HVB), insured persons with health insurance 82 Monthly charge no more than € 333.16 (§ 5 Abs. 2 ASVG) 83 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB (2006). Social security data (contributions) in the Austrian Social Insurance 2006. cut-off-date 1 January 2006, Version 13.02.2006 84 Haydn, R. (2005), ″Multiple insurance in Austrian Social insurance, individual-related statistics 2004.″ Soziale Sicherheit 2, pp. 74-82. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 34 these groups then the procedure is similar to that for tourists, whose access to services is basically unrestricted, but the share of costs to be paid is on the one hand linked with the existence of a bilateral agreement with Austria and on the other hand the type of service called upon. In the case of, for example, EU citizens, as well as citizens of the European Economic Area and Switzerland the claim is documented by means of the European Health Insurance Card (formerly E111 certificate) for care and medical services received during the temporary stay in Austria, which must be presented when visiting a doctor. Asylum seekers under federal supervision as well as sick and needy asylum seekers are covered by social health insurance as long as their place of residence is in Austria and they do not perform any activity which would reason compulsory insurance (see also Section 3.5 “Access to care for asylum seekers”). Entitlement to use services Access to services is dependent on whether a valid entitlement to services is in existence at the time of claiming for benefits. The scope of services, as well as any preconditions for claiming benefits, is regulated by various social insurance laws. Should an insured person not have their e-card with them then this does not prevent them from calling upon services (see Section 2.3.3 “e-Card”). The fact that some doctors demand a deposit fee when a card is not presented could be seen as a barrier. To some extent, this approach was already practiced when a health insurance voucher was not presented under the previous system. Not insured persons In 2003 the Ministry of Health and Women carried out a study to determine and record those persons not insured that drew the following conclusions:85 “At the end of June 2003 up to 205,000 people from the age of 15 years (3.1% of the resident population from age 15 years) are not covered by national health insurance. Of these up to 160,000 people from the age of 15 years (up to 2.4% of the resident population from the age of 15 years) are without any (registered) entitlement to services in case of illness (they also have no obligatory health insurance under private law, no (registered) entitlement to medical help, no health care through judiciary institutions).86 • Compared with the respective proportion of the population, in both groups there are very few men and the number of people aged 15-29 years disproportionately high. • Based on secondary analysis of a representative WHO study there are sufficient grounds to presume that, amongst those not health insured, a large proportion of people do not have Austrian nationality and have a low level of education compared with their respective proportion of the general population. • The total number of (registered) persons entitled to medical help (excluding self-insured) was about 19,000 in December 2002. • Compared to their respective portion of the general population men, people in the age groups 40– 49 and 50–59 years as well as foreign nationals are disproportionately highly represented. • The total expenditure for medical help (excl. self-insurance contributions) was around €50 million in 2002 (based on available data). • In addition there were around 4000 self-insured persons in December 2002, for whom the social security funds paid the contributions. • Compared to the respective portion of the general population, here women, the over 50s (esp. over 70 years) as well as (to a limited extent) Austrians are disproportionately represented. • The sum of the health insurance contributions paid by the social security funds was around €10 million in 2002 (based on available data).” 85 Federal Ministry of Health and Women (2003). Quantitative and qualitative assessment and analysis of individuals not covered by health insurance in Austria, Final report. 86 Maximum values LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 35 The report also presents reasons for temporary as well as permanent lack of insurance coverage. Models for the extension of access to health insurance are discussed. Self employed professionals/members of a pertaining to a Chamber (doctors, pharmacists, dentists, notaries, patent lawyers, solicitors, civil technicians, tax consultants, vets) who have opted for a private insurance scheme as well as their dependants are not covered by social insurance (17,000 persons in 2003). Insured who do not benefit from services Only a relatively low proportion of insured persons make no claim on services. In Austria at the end of 2004, 7,470,454 people were entitled to benefits covered by insurance funds according to LIVE.87 When those people entitled to benefits, but who died in 2004, are added to this number the total reaches 7,540,000 (plausible approximated value). Of these, 95% used at least one service from one of the areas of medical help or equivalent, medication or dental treatment, dental prosthesis.88 This means around 360,000 people have not used any type of health service.89 In their study published in 2004, Wurzer et al. reported that 84% of persons insured with the Carinthian sickness fund received one or more services in 2002.90 Compared to the overall percentage this is lower although in this study all service areas were taken into account. The motivation not to access services of the national health insurance may be divided into two categories: a) The insured person does not need or want them: - The insured person is healthy and does not require any medical services The services that the insured person would like to use, are not covered by the scope of services offered by health insurance (e.g. oral hygiene at the dentist, in part alternative therapies, cosmetic surgery) and are therefore paid privately (with or without the cover of a private health insurance) The insured person treats him/herself and uses non-prescription medicines (OTC medicines) The insured person seeks medical advice or assistance from family or friends who work in the field of health care and do not charge for their services b) The insured person cannot access them: - The insured person does not fulfil the requirements for entitlement (e.g. for access to medical rehabilitation measures91) The insured person cannot or does not wish to use services on financial grounds The insured person cannot or does not want to use services via social insurance due to long waiting times and accesses a private provider (without subsequently submitting the bill to the health insurance for reimbursement of costs) The insured person does not use a service because they do not know that it is offered/ covered by the health insurance (lack of information). The insured person cannot or does not access services due to cultural reasons Access to a particular service is not possible for the insured person on geographical grounds o The resources are not reachable within a reasonable amount of time92 87 LIVE = Service information for insured persons (Leistungs-Informationen für Versicherte) , 7,704,292 records with a social insurance number (not including entitled persons insured by the Insurance of the Austrian Railway Industry and health care establishments as well as persons eligible for benefits without services). Multiple-insured persons were consolidated. 88 90% at least one service in the field of medical attendance, 73% in the field of medication and 47% in the field of dental treatment & dental prosthesis 89 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (HVB), basic data for the LIVE – analysis 2004. received 18/04/2006 90 Wurzer, A., Robinig, R., Rodler, J. (2004). User charges, a review for orientation. Klagenfurt, Regional sickness fund of Carinthia. 91 When claiming to need rehabilitation the diagnosis of the patient has to be such that treatment in a rehabilitation clinic will either maintain the effect of the treatment the patient received before (e.g. in a hospital) or will alleviate any consequences of the illness. The aim is to restore the patients’ health to such an extent that they won’t need continuous care. Legal requirements see § 154a ASVG LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 36 The treatment is not available in Austria in the form required and it is not possible to travel abroad. This situation is not common. o The insured travels abroad and utilizes health care services which he however, upon return, does not bill his health insurance fund (a refund is not requested) The insured does not realise they require medical services (e.g. because of mental illness) or, because of their illness, refuses any form of medical assistance.93 o - Non- insured persons who benefit from services In principal all providers of health care services in Austria are, independent of the insurance status of the patient, obliged to provide assistance in case of emergency. There are only a few national health insurance services which may potentially be utilized without the need for compulsory insurance or joint insurance. Within this category of services is preventive health or health examination. For non-insured persons their costs are covered by the health insurance funds who receive reimbursement from the federation at a later date, or “Mother-Child-Pass” examinations, which, for non-insured persons, are paid in full by the “Fund for Balancing Family Burden” (FLAF).94 For human genetic precautionary measures, especially genetic family consultation, prenatal diagnosis and cyto-genetic examinations the costs for non-insured persons are carried by the federation95. Furthermore cash reimbursements for the non-insured exist for FSME vaccinations (for tick-borne encephalitis ).96 State-run hospitals are, in accordance with § 22 Abs. 2 KAKuG, obliged to admit sick people. People without health insurance coverage are attended as private payers and must pay the general care charges. If this is not possible the social support of the federal states steps in, which, depending on the provisions of the legal requirements in the federal state concerned, recovers the payment from the patient or relatives.97 In certain circumstances child benefit is also granted to non-insured persons, or people who have never worked, such as, housewives/house husbands, students or those receiving minimum wage. Entitlement and level of child benefit is linked with attendance at the “mother-child-pass” examinations. People drawing child benefit are part insured by the national health insurance. Child benefit is financed by the “Fund for Balancing Family Burden”. Individuals who are not covered Usually citizens in Austria do not have the option of deciding if they would like to join social insurance or not. Either they meet the prerequisites for statutory insurance (full- or partial insurance) and are thus automatically insured or they meet the requirements to be insured as dependants or they do not fulfil either of the conditions stated above. The principle of subsidiarity is applied; anybody not covered by compulsory insurance or by insurance as a dependant does not meet the legal requirements to be protected by social insurance. However in all 92 Geographical availability of treatment in case of an emergency is available according to international standards. Other services (e.g. specialists) may exhibit varying local access but are in principle available for insured without significant restrictions. Commuting time of about 1.5 hours may occasionally be necessary but is judged to be acceptable. (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB. Dr. Endel, 9 August 2006, telephone) 93 An examination of the characteristics of those insured persons who do not call upon services available through the health insurance could have been conducted by analyzing data from the health insurance funds (probably from FOKO - Folgekostenrechnung, analysis of follow-up costs), but it was not initiated within the framework of this study due to time and resource constraints. 94 Financed by contributions from employers, contributions from land and forestry businesses, federal budget, social services of the federal states and repaid services (www.bmsg.gv.at) 95 Federal Ministry of Social Insurance, Generations and Consumer Protection (2003). Report describing the situation of disabled persons in Austria. Vienna. Accessed at: http://www.bmsg.gv.at/cms/site/attachments/4/7/1/CH0007/CMS1058781346290/behindertenbericht.pdf, on 07/04/2006 96 Regional sickness fund of Vorarlberg, accessed at www.vgkk.at on 07/04/06 97 Dr. Felix, (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). 10 April 2006 (via email) LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 37 branches of social insurance (health, accident and pension insurance) the option of voluntary insurance is available. Factors excluding individuals from social insurance coverage are for example: • Their employment has only secondary significance– in the ASVG (earnings below a certain threshold (€333.16 per month, €25.59 per day)98 • Their income is below a certain threshold (GSVG): €6453.36 or €3997.92 respectively, depending on if the individual exercises only the self-employed occupation (first threshold) or if another occupation is held or alternatively any of the following financial benefits are consumed: pension according to the B-KUVG (Ruhe- oder Versorgungsgenßs), child care benefit or any other financial benefit resulting from statutory health- or unemployment insurance (second threshold) 99 • The professional organization of the insured has chosen to opt out of social insurance according to § 5 GSVG (amongst others physicians, veterinary doctors) • Individuals who are only insured in one or two branches of social insurance (partial insurance), for instance recipients of a pension, persons serving military service • Members of orders and congregations of the catholic church as well as of institutions belonging to the evangelic deaconry • Individuals whose main residence is abroad (exemptions include studies, professional training as a dependant, deployment, employees of an embassy, foreign companies, employees in the field of transportation, development workers) • The insured is already insured under another law (covered as a dependant) • A dependent child older than 27 years100 Individuals who are not covered by compulsory social insurance may take out voluntary insurance (with a private insurance company or with a social insurance fund). Social insurance can only verify the occupation of self-employed after these have registered with the tax authorities. They are obliged to register with the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business within 4 weeks after fulfilment of the criteria for compulsory insurance (§ 18 GSVG). If they do not do so financial penalties can come into effect. 2.3.3 The e-card With the 56th amendment of the ASVG the Main Association of Austrian Social Insurance Institutions (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB) was assigned the responsibility of creating an e-card for social insurance which should be the basis of an electronic administration system (elektronisches Verwaltungssystem, ELSY). Administrative processes ought to, to the extent possible, be performed without paper documents (§ 31 a (1) ASVG). In the first expansion stage the chip card should replace all types of health insurance voucher. The card is to be presented by the insured whenever using the services of a contract partner of social insurance (§ 31 c (1) ASVG).101 From the 1st January 2003 contract doctors (based on the 59th amendment of the ASVG) and from 1st January 2004 other contract partners (based on § 349a ASVG) were obliged to bill provided services 98 Austrian Social Insurance, accessed at www.sozialversicherung.at low-income-earners (below € 333.16 per month) are only insured with accident insurance 99 Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA), accessed at: www.sva.at 100 Children older than 18 years can be insured as dependants if they are predominantly occupied by educational or professional training (e.g. university). This is possible until they are 27 years old. After that they may only be insured as dependants in case they are unemployed (limited to 2 years) or unfit to work (limited to duration of inability to work). 101 e-card website, accessed at: www.chipkarte.at on 03/03/2006 General Social Insurance Act, ASVG Schober, I. (2005). ″Plan for the introduction of the e-card and preparations within social insurance.″ Soziale Sicherheit 1, pp. 19-22 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 38 electronically with their insurance fund. Fulfilling this legal requirement is facilitated by the fact that the data from the e-card system can be transferred to the software of the physician. Further legal basis are the SVÄG and the E-GovG. Distribution of e-cards to the insured102 Issuing of the e-card is regulated by law, amongst other in § 31b para.3 ASVG. The e-card is sent to the insured automatically (without application) by mail. Only those individuals (insured and their entitled dependants) for which an entitlement in health insurance, according to one of the social insurance laws (ASVG, B-KUVG, BSVG, GSVG, FSVG), was verified at a certain point in time or those covered by one of the health care establishments103 (Krankenfürsorgeanstalten, KFA: KFA of the employees of the city of Vienna, KFA of the civil servants of the provincial capital Graz, KFA of the civil servants of the city of Villach, KFA of the magistrate’s civil servants of the provincial capital Salzburg) received an e-card. The insured has to reside within the boarders of the country. In case he didn’t have any entitlement at the above mentioned point in time he receives the card by mail as soon as entitlement exists. Having an e-card does not automatically mean that a person is insured. Entitlement status can be verified by using the card to access the system (e.g. when consulting a physician). The nationwide rollout in Austria (about 8.1 million cards104) took place between May and November 2005, in weekly stages for different regions. Nationwide use was ensured by January 2006 Cost Social insurance finances the e-card from its own funds. According to § 135, para.3 ASVG a yearly service charge of €10.00 is levied (for each insured). The employer levies the service charge which is due by November 15 and pays it to the respective sickness fund, independently of the employee actually having an e-card or not (it is assumed that most of the employed persons have one). The service charge is to be paid, regardless of amount/number of services actually consumed by the insured which results in a relief for critically ill persons or those suffering from a chronic illness. Individuals paying a co-payment (selfemployed, civil servants) are not obliged to pay the service charge. The service charge is only accrued for employed persons who are insured based on the ASVG and who so far had to pay the charge for a health insurance voucher when visiting a physician. Individuals receiving child care benefits, sickness- or maternity benefits receive the bill for the service charge from their respective sickness fund. Multiple insured persons initially pay for each insurance entitlement, they may however ask for a refund of the excess payment at their concerned sickness fund when presenting the payment documents. This procedure is conducted by means of an informal claim. Children or pensioners with multiple insurance do not pay any service charge. All revenue generated by the service charge is invested in health insurance benefits. The service charge includes the usage of the e-card as a citizen card105 (Bürgerkarte). A gadget to read the card costs the insured €20.00, the software is provided free of charge. Areas of application In the first stage of expansion the e-card only replaces the paper-health insurance voucher and verifies the patient’s entitlement towards the sickness fund and the contract physician in Austria with respect to utilising 102 Ms.Schober (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB) interview 11 November 2005 e-card website, accessed at: www. chipkarte.at on 03/03/2006 103 Insurance funds for employees of cities and municipalities not insured according to B-KUVG. 104 No author (2005), ″The dispatching of the e-card has been finished″, Soziale Sicherheit 12, pp. 504-506 105 The citizen card offers individuals more convenience, more security and more speed. Using it enables the identification of persons and authentication via electronic signature. With the card amongst many other services administrative processes (communication with authorities and companies) can be handled from at home, for instance secure access of forms, registrations (e.g. at www. finanz.at), ciphering and securing documents. For further information, refer to www.buergerkarte.at LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 39 services of contract physicians in real time.106 In addition the e-card infrastructure is used to handle the prior authorization for pharmaceuticals (Arzneimittelbewilligungsservice, ABS). In the future further functions should be made possible through which the card will become the central key of access for services provided by social insurance and within the health care system. It is planned to include and electronically link all providers. The administration of the prior authorisation of medication takes place using the e-card infrastructure. Further services (e.g. e-prescription) are planned and are described at a later point. Currently only personal data of the card owner such as name, title and social insurance number have been saved on the card. On the front side the card is provided with a card sequence number, the telephone number of the service line, the web address of social insurance and a chip which contains information about sex and date of birth. The card is valid for an unlimited amount of time which does however not imply that a person is constantly insured. The back of the e-card serves as European health insurance card (EHIC) and is not electronic. It replaces the treatment voucher (before E 111 form) to utilize physician services during temporary stays in the EU member states, EEA-states and Switzerland and is valid for up to 10 years. The card itself does not carry application data but acts as a key card (it has various signature functions) to grant access to applications, services or data for the card owner himself or entitled third parties (e.g. physicians). When the card is read, the physician has access to the following data (which is saved in the operation centre (Betriebszentrale) of the e-card system: name, insurance status (insured/not insured), insurance category (e.g. pensioner), type of entitlement (in cash or in kind), exemption of charges (prescription charges, exemption of co-payments), consultation of a physician of the same specialty in the same quarter. To be able to read the data actually two cards, namely the e-card of the insured as well as the o-card (practice card of the physician – secured by PIN) of the physician have to interact logically. This is supposed to prevent fraud. Assignments and referrals performed by the first contact health practitioner (Erstbehandler) have to still be taken along in paper form. In this situation the e-card is like a verification of entitlement and is to be presented together with the referral note.107 The E 112 form (travelling only in order to utilize a certain type of treatment in one of the formerly mentioned countries) still has to be issued regularly. The infrastructure of the e-card makes an electronic linking of all physicians (contract partners) possible. The extension of the system in order to include other providers such as hospitals and outpatient departments is planned; the inclusion of all providers is the overall vision. The secure transfer of data which has to be protected is facilitated by various signature functions. Types of signature functions108 Simple signature (SV signature) without PIN input allows the exchange data between practice and central system. Administration signature according to § 25 E-Government law (PIN signature) i.e. citizen card signature: for this a certificate is necessary – the application can be directed at the Hauptverband or any other appropriate provider of certificate services (area of application: E-Government, activities within administration) and is free of charge. The signature is a secure signature towards the outside (area of application: private services, signing of contracts) – an application associated with some costs. It is planned that the following functions will be added to the e-card :109 106 Krüger-Brand, H. (2004). ″The e-card starts in Austria.″ Deutsches Ärzteblatt 101:49, pp. 3318-3319 e-card Website, accessed at: www. chipkarte.at on 03/03/2006 108 Ms.Schober (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). Interview 11 November 2005 e-card website, accessed at: www. chipkarte.at on 03/03/2006 Otter, H. (2004). ″The e-card as citizen card in e-government.″ Soziale Sicherheit 12, pp. 499-501 109 Medical Chamber of Vienna (Eds.) (2005). E-card administrative, accessed at http://www.aekwien.or.at/media/ecard_administrativ.pdf on 12/09/2006 107 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 40 • • • • • • • • • Integrating hospitals and other contract partners into the system Electronic prescription (e-prescription) Extending the area of application of the e-card to a recognised health-chipcard in the EU Handling of registration in social insurance Using the e-card for transferring sensitive health data (e.g. transmission of medical records) Substituting the paper-referral note by an electronic referral note (2006 or 2007) Storing emergency data (on the card or accessible via a server) Using the e-card for e-government and eSV According to the law biometric data are to be upgraded via a chip beginning in 2010 Information relevant for the e-card which can be accessed in the electronic data processing centre (Rechenzentrum) can be extended arbitrarily as long as they are in accordance with the legal provisions (Health Care Telematics Act). The legal basis for the storage of emergency data was created by the 59th amendment of the ASVG. The storage is technically feasible. Before actually executing this step a whole range of questions still have to be clarified. Improvements through the e-card The e-card is an infrastructure project because it provides a basis for telecommunication in the health care system and consequently also for a range of forward-looking follow-up projects. By means of the e-card all contract partners (doctors, institutes, etc.) are linked electronically through a secure health care information network (Gesundheitsinformationsnetz, GIN). The project is not only advantageous for social insurance but for the entire economy, the present network makes it possible to transfer diagnostic findings. Involved stakeholders benefit from the introduction of the e-card in different ways. Results of two public opinion surveys performed in September and November 2005 show that the Austrian population are supportive of the e-card and that physicians increasingly accept it.110 The employer no longer has to issue health insurance vouchers but only has to levy the service charge once a year. The card saves time and money with respect to administration (no filling out or repeated requesting of health insurance vouchers). Equally the issuing of health insurance vouchers for holidays ceases to exist. Social insurance was however allocated the responsibility for all sorts of administrative duties related to the e-card such as the issuing or posting of the card. Patients only need their personal e-card (and if need be a referral note) when consulting a doctor. Seeing the employer or the public employment service (Arbeitsmarktservice, AMS) is no longer necessary. The patient’s privacy is better protected (it is not required to inform the employer every time before consulting a physician). Because of the convenient format the patient can always carry the card with him and will most likely not forget it as often as the health insurance voucher. In the case of multiple insurance, as yet, the patient has the right to choose the sickness fund through which he accesses the service. The e-card does not interfere with this existing regulation. The card has sufficient storage space for future applications and may be used as a citizen card (Bürgerkarte).111 The citizen card offers individuals more convenience, more security and more speed. With the card amongst many other services administrative processes can be handled from at home, for instance secure access of forms, registrations (e.g. at www. finanz.at), ciphering and securing documents. Otter, H. (2004). ″ The e-card as citizen card in e-government.″ Soziale Sicherheit 12, pp. 499-501 Bugner, W.M. (2004). ″The infrastructural project of the e-card system of Austrian Social insurance in practice.″ Soziale Sicherheit 12, pp. 488-492 110 Anonymous (2005), ″ The dispatching of the e-card has been finished ″, Soziale Sicherheit 12, pp. 504-506 111 For more information on the Austrian Citizen Card, view http://www.buergerkarte.at/index_en.html LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 41 Using the administrative signature of the citizen card makes it furthermore possible to request personal data from the social insurance web portal (progression of insurance (Versicherungsverlauf), status of insurance). This facilitates communication between the insured and the insurance fund. By using the e-card the physician can immediately tell if a patient has insurance coverage or not. Data is updated regularly. Because patients will probably not forget the e-card as often as the health insurance voucher the doctor will not be required to fill out substitute insurance vouchers. Physicians who possess the e-card infrastructure have not automatically signed a contract with social insurance. In addition to reducing administration costs by means of the above mentioned mechanisms the process of billing is facilitated for the doctor because he is now able to transfer data from the e-card server to his billing software. Furthermore the physician is, within the context of the e-card, granted a range of additional services such as secure Internet-access or banking-access or use of email.112 Overall, transparency of services is increased by the e-card system. Moreover, security of data is ensured by means of up-to-date technology. Forgetting / losing the e-card or theft In case the insured forgot or lost their e-card, health care services may still be consumed. The patient is at any disadvantage, provided that they know their insurance number (i.e. a query system for social insurance numbers is part of the e-card system). The insured has to communicate the number to the doctor who then introduces it into the system and signs the consultation with his practice card (Ordinationskarte). The card must be brought along at the next visit. The physician is allowed to charge the patients a deposit fee (as previously for forgotten insurance vouchers). Patients are obliged to confirm their entitlement with a signature. Newly born are special cases as their e-cards are not automatically issued with their birth. As soon as the birth of the child is communicated to a civil registry office this is automatically passed on to the insurance carrier which initiates the issuing of an insurance number and e-card. Depending on the insurance fund a certain amount of consultations may be billed without an e-card (as before, when the contract partner was entitled to only issue a definite amount of substitute insurance vouchers). Further consultations can be saved, with regard to billing the physician has to contact his insurance fund though. It is of the physician’s own interest to keep this number as low as possible; otherwise he takes a risk in the situation of billing the services provided. In the course of a follow-up consultation or also without consultation the “without-card-limit” is corrected automatically.113 In case the insured would like to utilize benefits abroad he has to fill out an entitlement form at his respective insurance fund. Lacking entitlement to social health insurance benefits The following population groups do not have an e-card114: • • Low income earners (below €333.16 per month or €25.59 per day (2006)) Recipients of social welfare benefits; however, the requirements according to federal law for social benefits recipients to obtain an e-card were recently created. 112 Ferchner, S. (2005). ″E-card: looking into the future.″, Ärztemagazin 12, accessed at http://www.medizinmedien.info/dynasite.cfm?dssid=4169&dsmid=62700&dspaid=473300 on 12/09/2006 Ms.Schober (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). Interview 11 November 2005 Bugner, W.M. (2004). ″ The infrastructural project of the e-card system of Austrian Social insurance in practice.″ Soziale Sicherheit 12, pp. 488-492 Ms. Resch (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). Interview 29 June 2006 114 Ms.Schober (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). Interview 11 November 2005 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 42 • • • • Those who opt out from the statutory scheme (persons who can, according to § 5 GSVG, choose between statutory social health insurance and private health insurance) – they are not interested in participating Cross-border commuters (complicated cases with foreign insurance carriers, etc.) Asylum seekers; however it is planned that the doctor receives the insurance number and can then check entitlement as well as bill services. Health care establishments115 (Krankenfürsorgeanstalten): So far only a couple of health care establishments (Krankenfürsorgeanstalten) are part of the e-card project and even these in varying intensity. Some have fully adopted the card, others only use the EKVK the European Health Insurance Card. The reason for this is that this group of insured did not have the system of health insurance vouchers (exception: for travelling abroad – E111 form) but was billed directly by the health care provider, being reimbursed at a later stage by their insurer. The inclusion of the remaining health care establishments will most likely take place in stages.116 2.4 Progressivity of financing Payments are progressive if the higher income groups pay disproportionately more than those on lower income. The distribution of financial burden and the degree of progressivity and regressivity differs across funding sources. Health care payments are progressive if the share of health care payments in gross income increases with gross income, and they are regressive if payments decrease with income117. Furthermore, the extent to which a funding system will redistribute income from the higher to the lower income groups depends on both the progressivity of revenue collection and the incidence of public spending. It is important to consider these two factors, as failure to do so may reveal an inaccurate picture of fairness. For example, in order to achieve the same redistributive effect as a progressive system, a proportional system must unequally distribute benefits.118 It could be argued that a less progressive system in which public spending benefits the lower income groups disproportionately may create a better situation for low-income people than in a more progressive system but with less public spending for the poor. Public spending on health care may be difficult to separate from overall public spending that may also be redistributing revenue. A longitudinal perspective is needed to understand the redistributive effect of a health care system in order to account for redistribution between periods of wealth and periods of poverty over a lifetime. While most redistribution studies focus on one point in time, the few longitudinal studies generally show a redistribution from ‘lifetime richest’ to ‘lifetime poorest’, but the redistribution is relatively flat.119 Among the different types of taxation, there are different degrees of progressivity. Wagstaff et al. studied the progressivity of health care financing in OECD countries.120 This study found that direct taxes were progressive in all countries, while indirect taxes were regressive in all countries except Spain in 1980 (which may result from higher value-added taxes on luxury goods). Also, among the EU member states, direct taxes are progressively distributed while indirect taxes are regressive according to Kakwani indices.121 Indirect taxes constitute a larger proportion of income of poor people than wealthier people. For example, in the UK, lower income households pay a greater proportion of their income on indirect taxes (32 115 Health insurance fund of individuals employed by a municipality or a city under public law. ORF Oberösterreich (2006) Electronic health insurance voucher, no e-card for civil servants of the federal states, accessed at:: http://ooe.orf.at/stories/86505/ on 31/01/2006 117 D De Graeve and T Van Ourti, The Distributional Impact of Health Financing in Europe: A Review (Oxford: Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 2003). 118 R Ervik, The Redistributive Aim of Social Policy: A Comparative Analysis of Taxes, Tax Expenditure Transfers and Direct Transfers in Eight Countries (New York: Syracuse University, 1998). 119 Mossialos and Dixon, eds., Funding Health Care: Options for Europe. 120 A Wagstaff, E van Doorslaer, and van der Burg H, eds., Equity in the Finance and Delivery of Health Care: An International Perspective (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). 121 Ibid. 116 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 43 per cent) than higher income households (11 per cent).122 In examining the tax system as a whole, in 19981999, the UK tax system was slightly regressive due to indirect taxes, with the lowest income quintile paying 40 per cent of income in taxes, while the highest income quintile paid 36 per cent of their income on taxes.123 The extent of progressivity of income taxation depends on the number and rates of marginal tax bands, where fewer tax bands and low marginal tax rates will create a regressive system. Income tax in France, Germany, the Netherlands, Sweden and the UK appears to be progressive, with income being transferred from the highest income quintile to the rest of the population124. Figure 2.3 shows the relationship between progressivity (measured by the Kakwani index) and the proportion of funding through taxation; tax-funded systems are more progressive than countries relying more on social and private insurance like the Netherlands, Germany, Switzerland and the United States. Figure 2.3 Estimates of progressivity (Kakwani Progressivity Index) of total health spending based on % financed by tax in the 1980s and 1990s, selected European countries Note: DK, Denmark (1981,1987); FI, Finland (1990, 1996); F, France (1984, 1989) D, Germany (1989); I, Italy (1991); NE, Netherlands (1987, 1992); P, Portugal (1990); E, Spain (1980, 1990); SW, Sweden (1980, 1990); CH, Switzerland (1982, 1992); UK (1993); US (1987). Source: Wagstaff et al 1999 National taxation has been found to be a more progressive system of financing than local taxation. Wagstaff et al. put forth evidence showing that national taxation in Denmark, Finland and Sweden is more progressive than in countries with decentralised tax collection.125 Also in Finland, an increase in the average rate of local income taxes led to a decline in progressivity in the early 1990s.126 122 Glennerster, Paying for Welfare: Towards 2000. 3rd Ed. Commission on Taxation and Citizenship, "Paying for Progress: A New Politics of Tax for Public Spending." 124 S Zandvakili, "Income Distribution and Redistribution through Taxation: An International Comparison," Empirical Economics 19 (1994). 125 Wagstaff, van Doorslaer, and H, eds., Equity in the Finance and Delivery of Health Care: An International Perspective. 126 J Klavus and U Hakkinen, "Micro-Level Analysis of Distributional Changes in Health Care Financing in Finland," Journal of Health Services Research and Policy 3, no. 1 (1998). 123 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 44 In terms of the redistributive effect of tax and benefit systems, there is considerable variance across countries. Comparing eight countries in the 1990s, Sweden redistributed the most, reducing income inequality by 50 per cent, followed by Denmark and Germany, reducing inequalities by more than 40% and the UK redistributed the least, with a 35% reduction in inequalities. It is likely that the observed redistribution resulted more from social transfers than taxation.127 Within social health insurance systems, the degree of fairness, or equity, depends on whether or not the contributions are mandatory. It also depends on the existence of ceilings for contribution rates; payments are progressive up to a ceiling, and then regressive. In cases where individuals are either not allowed, as in the Netherlands, or are not obliged, as in Germany, to stay in the public system, the payments become regressive.128 In the Netherlands, about 31% of the population is required to opt out, which leads to a high concentration of people on lower incomes and higher risk in the statutory health insurance schemes.129 In Germany, about 21% of the population can choose to opt out, however, only 7% choose to be fully covered with private insurance. The social health insurance systems in Germany and the Netherlands have been found to be regressive.130 Kakwani indices also demonstrate that German and Dutch financing systems are regressive.131Conversely, in France, with the recently introduced compulsory statutory health insurance scheme (in 1999) which offers insurance for user charges and expanded the contribution basis to include total income of employees, there is a higher degree of risk pooling which increases equity. The redistributive effect of social insurance funding has been studied in Germany. Three types of interpersonal redistribution are seen in Germany: (1) due to varying health risks, there is considerable horizontal and vertical redistribution with the renunciation of experience rating; (2) dependents are insured, suggesting redistribution from single people and couples to people in large families, in addition all insured people are equally entitled to health care services, independent of previous contributions; (3) intergenerational redistribution between employed and retired people.132 However, it is argued that redistribution is more effective in a tax-funded system due to limited income equalization through social health insurance and negative economic effects of linking insurance contributions to earnings.133 Private funding creates inequity because it shifts the funding burden away from population-based riskpooling arrangements, in which people contribute through taxation or social health insurance on the basis of their ability to pay, towards out-of-pocket payments by individuals and households, with a pro-rich distributive impact.134 Furthermore, international comparisons of progressivity in health care funding reveal that health care systems that are largely privately funded are more regressive than those in which funding is predominantly public.135 127 Ervik, The Redistributive Aim of Social Policy: A Comparative Analysis of Taxes, Tax Expenditure Transfers and Direct Transfers in Eight Countries. 128 De Graeve and Van Ourti, The Distributional Impact of Health Financing in Europe: A Review. 129 Mossialos and Dixon, eds., Funding Health Care: Options for Europe. 130 Wagstaff, van Doorslaer, and H, eds., Equity in the Finance and Delivery of Health Care: An International Perspective. 131 De Graeve and Van Ourti, The Distributional Impact of Health Financing in Europe: A Review. 132 K Hinrichs, "Social Insurances and the Culture of Solidarity: The Moral Infrastructure of Interpersonal Redistributions - with Special Reference to the German Health Care System.," (Bremen:: Centre for Social Policy Research, University of Bremen, 1997). 133 P.F. Lutz and U. Schneider, "Der Soziale Ausgleich in Der Gesetzlichen Krankenversicherung [Income Redistribution under Germany's Statutory Health Insurance Scheme]," Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 217, no. 6 (1998). 134 A Creese, "User Fees: They Don't Reduce Costs and They Increase Inequity [Editorial]." British Medical Journal 315, no. 7102 (1997), R.G Evans and M.L Barer, "User Fees for Health Care: Why a Bad Idea Keeps Coming Back (or, What's Health Got to Do with It?)," Canadian Journal on Aging . 14, no. 2 (1995). 135 In a regressive funding system the poor spend a greater proportion of their income on health care than the rich; in a proportionate funding system everybody spends the same proportion; in a progressive funding system the rich spend a greater proportion than the poor. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 45 Substitutive insurance, as in Germany and the Netherlands, is regressive because those who remain in the statutory health insurance scheme have lower incomes and will have to pay higher premiums to compensate for the higher risk and lower average income of subscribers. Also, while private health insurance has been found to be regressive in France, Ireland and Spain, contributions appear to be proportional to income in Finland and even progressive in Denmark, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal and the UK.136 Some argue that by encouraging (or forcing) high income individuals to purchase private health insurance, this will make the financing system more progressive, since the rich will pay proportionately more than the poor. However, private health insurance may skew the provision of services to favour the higher income groups. The WHO World Health Report 2000 devised a measure of fairness of health care financing; however data on Austria were unfortunately not available. This formula is based on the goal that health care payments should not be linked to consumption and that a proportional relationship should exist between ability to pay and health care payments. Thus, a fair system of financing would be one where the ratio of total health contribution to total non-food spending is identical for all households, independent of income, health status and utilization; the index would take a value of 1. Table 2.10 shows that according to this formula, all 15 countries have around the same, high, degree of fairness (including the US). This apparent insensitivity is one of many critiques of this method, along with the use of estimation by the WHO, rather than explicit calculation of the values for each country.137 Table 2.10 Fairness of financial contribution to health systems: estimates for 1997 Country Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom US Index 0.979 0.979 0.977 0.971 0.978 0.963 0.978 0.961 0.973 0.951 0.971 0.976 0.964 0.977 0.954 Uncertainty Interval 0.964-0.991 0.964-0.991 0.961-0.990 0.956-0.983 0.964-0.989 0.946-0.978 0.965-0.989 0.935-0.981 0.959-0.985 0.932-0.968 0.956-0.984 0.959-0.990 0.948-0.979 0.963-0.988 0.929-0.974 Source: WHO World Health Report 2000 136 Wagstaff, van Doorslaer, and H, eds., Equity in the Finance and Delivery of Health Care: An International Perspective. 137 De Graeve and Van Ourti, The Distributional Impact of Health Financing in Europe: A Review, P Musgrove, "Judging Health Systems: Reflections on Who's Methods," The Lancet 361 (2003), A Wagstaff, "Reflections on and Alternatives to Who's Fairness of Financial Contribution Index," Health Economics 11 (2002). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 46 2.4.1 Progressivity of financing in the Austrian health system Proportion of national income represented by total earnings from employment (wage quota) The income generated by wages constitutes around 70% of national income and is thereby the most important income source.138 During the 1970s the wage quota increased, but fell during the 1980s and 1990s (see Figure 2.4). The adjusted wage quota dropped from 71% (1981) to 58.5% (2003). The quota of benefits increased from 29% to 41.5% of GDP. Income on assets has gained in importance, though taxation of this type of income has not been adjusted.139 The implication of a reduction in the wage quota for social insurance is a reduction in social insurance contributions i.e. an erosion of the contributions. GDP increased by 31.4% between 1993 and 2000 and the sum of wages and income by 23.8%. Revenue generated by social insurance contributions in the branch of health insurance rose by 26% whilst the expenditures in this area increased by 32.3%.140 Wages depicted a smaller increase than GDP, expenditures of social health insurance went up more than the GDP. This is a very crucial situation for social insurance because revenue rises at a lower rate than expenditures. In such a situation it is important for social insurance to create new options for acquiring funds, such as including income generated through assets in the contribution base. Figure 2.4 Development of wage quota Source: Statistik Austria, WIFO (Juni 2005), AK OÖ; not standardized wage quota as a share of the income of dependent employees (sum of gross wage and income plus social insurance contributions of the employer) of the income of the population in steps of four years, yearly from 2002 onwards, incl. prognosis for 2005 and 2006 138 Guger, A., Marterbauer, M.. (2004). ″The long term development of income distribution in Austria.″ Österreichisches Wirtschaftsforschungsinstitut, pp. 254-276, accessed at http://www.bmsg.gv.at/cms/site/attachments/9/2/3/CH0338/CMS1064227005975/12_einkommen.pdf, on 15/06/2006 139 Guger, A., Marterbauer, M. (2004). ″The long term development of income distribution in Austria.″ Österreichisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung, pp. 1-47 140 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2001). Working paper to create a sufficient funding base for social health insurance and to ensure a high level of care in the Austrian health care system in the future in Zechmeister, I., Meichenitsch, J., Hagleitner, J. (2004). ″Analysis and recommendations for the future funding of the health care system″, Study commissioned by the ARGE „Öllinger“/Grüner Klub im Nationalrat, p. 27. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 47 The lack of an integrated data base poses a considerable problem when evaluating distribution trends. Therefore, Guger and Marterbauer evaluated the changes in income distribution over time by means of approximation, including various data sources. Among others they used the social insurance contributions statistics of the Main Association of Austrian Insurance funds to analyse the development of income subject to social insurance contributions. This source of data excludes low wage earners and does not differentiate income generated by employees above a defined maximum earnings limit for chargeable contributions.141 Statistics show that the inequality in wage income has increased during the past three decades. Whilst the share of employees in the lowest quintile has remained fairly stable between 1970 and 2002 the share of employees in the top quintile has gone up by around 3 percent. The Gini coefficient demonstrates the increment in inequality (rise in the coefficient).142 Table 2.11 Development of the distribution of wage income subject to social insurance contributions (Employees excluding irredeemable civil servants (pragmatisierte Beamte)) Source: Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB Federal Ministry of Social Insurance, Generations and Consumer Protection, BMSGK (2003).Report on the social situation, Vienna Quintile = quntiles, Ginikoeffizient = gini coefficient, Insgesamt = Total, Arbeiter = worker, Angestellter = salaried employee 1) Change to yearly recording including supplementary grants (Sonderzahlungen) 2) Change in the breadth of the wage level in connection with the adoption of the Euro 3) An increase in the Gini coefficient stands for a rise in income inequality 4) A quintile includes a fifth of the wage recipients 5) Since the introduction of the general assessment of employees (Arbeitnehmerveranlagung) the wage tax statistics display a comprehensive analysis and includes thereafter around 400.000 more employees as the social insurance statistics; before that the wage tax statistic registered a couple of hunderedthousand employees less than the social insurance statistics. 6) In a detailed analysis of social insurance data Gusenleitner, Winter-Ebner and Zweimüller (1996) date the reversal of distribution trends to the year 1977. Earnings subject to wage tax To demonstrate the development of earnings which are subject to wage tax Guger and Marterbauer used the wage tax statistics which include low wage earners and also accounts for the income above the earnings limit for chargeable contributions. Since the 1970s income inequality Streuung) has been increasing, and during the second half of the 1990s a further increase in inequality took place. Between 1995 and 2002 the 141 Guger, A., Marterbauer, M.. (2004). ″ The long term development of income distribution in Austria.″ Österreichisches Wirtschaftsforschungsinstitut, pp. 254-276, accessed at http://www.bmsg.gv.at/cms/site/attachments/9/2/3/CH0338/CMS1064227005975/12_einkommen.pdf, on 15/06/2006 142 Guger, A., Marterbauer, M. (2004). ″The long term development of income distribution in Austria.″ Österreichisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung, pp. 1-47 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 48 share of wages in the first quartile has dropped and the share in the top quartile has been on the increase. During the time period under observation the Gini coefficient has risen, which implies that income inequality has increased.143 Table 2.12 Development of the distribution of the income of employees subject to wage tax (Employees including irredeemable civil servants (pragmatisierte Beamte)) Quintile = quinitiles, Qunitl = quntile, Ginikoeffizient = Gini coefficient, Arbeitnehmer/innen insgesamt = employees total 1) Reading assistance: In the year 1976 40.2% and in the year 2002 45.9% of all income subject to wage tax was attributed to the top 20% of income subject to wage tax. 2) An increase in the Gini coefficient stands for a rise in income inequality Source: Guger, Marterbauer Wage differences Wage differences between sectors have grown since the beginning of the 1980s, which is among other factors based in the rise in part time employment and irregular working hours. With respect to gender specific differences in income, considering the average over all economic sectors, the women’s median income is situated at 67.2% of the of men’s median income. Regarding the wage difference between sexes Austria has, based on the EURSTAT data, occupied the second rank after Great Britain among the EU 15.144 Table 2.13 Women’s median income as a percentage of men’s median income (With and without adjustment for working hours) Notes: Erwerbsttätige, nicht arbeitszeitbereinigt = gainful worker2), not adjusted for working hours Arbbeiterin = women workers; Angestellte = women employees; Erwerbsttätige, arbeitszeitbereinigt = gainful workers2) , adjusted for working hours 143 See also Biffl, G. (2003), Distribution of household income in Austria, WIFO Working Papers 214, pp. 1-42 Kalliauer, J., Moser, J., (2005). Data on the current distribution of income in Austria and Upper Austria, Press conference 15 September 2005 144 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 49 1) 50% earn more and 50% earn less than... 2) wage and salary recipients 3) adjusted for average of invested working hours Source: Guger, Marterbauer Guger and Materbauer list, among others, the following factors influencing the development of the distribution of income (wages): • • • • Shift in the structure in work demand towards qualified work Differences in the development of employment according to the qualification of the labour force Deregulation and flexibility of labour markets Inflow of foreign workers. The steady increase in the unequal distribution of household income can be explained by reduced household size, trends towards single households and the change in labour market participation of the household members. Weighted net per capita income (taking household size and composition into consideration) displays a considerably lower inequality in the distribution i.e. proving the influence of the above mentioned factors but also demonstrating that transfer payments such as family benefits are of considerable relevance in achieving a reduction in income inequalities. Table 2.14 Development of disposable net household income (Relative interquartile ranges1) in %) First block: Netto - Haushaltseinkommen = net-household income, Second block: Gewichtete Nettoeinkommen pro Kopf (Äquivalenzeinkommen) = weighted net household income per capita (equivalence income): for Arbeiter/in = Workers Angestellte = Employees Öffentlich Bedienstete = Civil servants Unselständige gesamt = All employees 1) The interquartile range measures by how much % the upper limit of the 3rd quartile (75% earn less and 25% earn more than...) surpasses the upper limit of the 1st quartile (25% earn less and 75% earn more than…) Source: Guger, Marterbauer Progressivity of the components of funding Taxes Tax revenue in Austria in the year 2002 constituted 44% of total government revenue and is converging towards the slightly lower EU average of 40.6%. Social insurance contributions (33.4% in 2002) and indirect taxes (consumption taxes) are high in comparison to taxes on assets (vermögensbezogene Steuern) (1.3% in 2002). Especially social insurance contributions145 are far above the EU-average of 28.1%. Income 145 Share of social insurance contributions of total tax revenue LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 50 taxation is progressive (maximal tax rates up to 50% for self employed and 44% for employed persons) and amounted to 22.8% of the taxation revenue (Gesamtsteuer- und Abgabenaufkommen) in 2002.146 Consumption taxes (e.g. VAT), representing the largest share of tax income, have a regressive effect because they affect low-income people relatively more than people with a high income. Especially non employed parts of the population such as pensioners are included in the funding system in a stronger way. Concerning consumption taxes a higher burden is placed on the consumers of services than on those not using the services. The share of taxes exercising a progressive effect (income tax, revenue tax, tax on assets) is relatively low. When calculating income tax an increasing tax rate is applied to higher income. However, as already mentioned before, a defined maximum tax rate constitutes the upper limit of taxation. Tax payments of citizens situated above this tax limit are regressive because people with a higher income pay a smaller relative share of their income for taxes than people with an income situated below or at the tax limit. In Austria the population paying taxes and the population subject to social insurance contributions is more or less the same because the system of statutory insurance includes all employees. Social insurance contributions Social insurance contributions are calculated based on the economic ability of the insured. The burden of insurance contributions of income increases linear i.e. proportionally until a defined earnings limit for chargeable contributions (every insured of a certain insurance fund pays the same contribution rate) is reached. The earnings ceiling for chargeable contributions according to the General Social Insurance Act (ASVG) was situated at 3,750 Euros per month in 2006.147 The insurance contributions of social insurance funds vary due to historical developments and differing benefits packages of sickness funds. Contribution rates for insured with an income above the earnings limit for chargeable contributions are regressive, i.e. insured with a higher contribution base spend a smaller share of their total income on social insurance contributions than insured whose contribution base is situated below or at the earnings limit for chargeable contributions. Hence people with a higher income are less affected economically than those with a lower income. It is possible to deduct social insurance contributions from the base for income tax. Voluntary health insurance payments may be set off tax liability as special expenses (up to a ceiling of 2,290.00 Euros per year).148 User charges Relative burden of different insured categories due to user charges is difficult to measure because of heterogeneous regulations in the different laws related to social insurance. Furthermore varying exemption criteria, benefits packages and reimbursement catalogues exacerbate objective comparison. User charges have a regressive effect. They primarily affect the persons utilising health care services. A study performed by the regional sickness fund in Carinthia shows that insured of the lower income categories have higher average user charges than those in upper income categories.149 Moreover, women of 146 Mayrhuber, C. (2005). Aspects of tax burdens and tax equity in Austria. presentation at the opening event for the ATTAC campaign "Fair Taxes – More for all" May 19 2005, accessed at: http://www.beigewum.at/_TCgi_Images/beigewum/20050705084435_Text_fair-steuern-19_05_05_fin.pdf, on 18/06/2006 147 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2006). Social security data (contributions) in the Austrian Social Insurance 2006, cut-off-date 1. January 2006, Version 13.02.2006 The limit was the same for the social insurance fund of the civil servants, of the railwaymen and miners and of the self-employed. The sickness fund of the farmers has at limit of 4,375 €. 148 Information provided by the HFP Tax advisor Plc. 19 June 2006 149 Wurzer, A., Robinig, R., Rodler, J. (2004). User charges, a review for orientation. Klagenfurt, Regional sickness fund of Carinthia. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 51 each income category pay significantly higher user charges than men because they utilize medical services more often. When looking at the relative share of their income (median gross income) spent on user charges, women with the lowest level of education display about the double amount of women with the highest level of education. For men this difference is roughly a fifth.150 In Austria there is a wide range of exemptions for user charges; these partially vary among the different sickness funds. The directive of the Hauptverband which bases exemption from user charges on the need of social protection is applicable to all insured.151 Equally the exemption by law is for persons suffering from notifiable communicable diseases. Redistribution: social insurance model and transfer payments Austrian social insurance is funded by a pay-as-you-go system. Social insurance contributions of the insured are not used to cover their personal demand for health care services but are immediately used for the funding of insurance benefits of the insured population. No capital is accumulated apart from a certain reserve. Insurance contributions are calculated based on the ability to pay of the insured person, not on his personal risk or usage of services (vertical equity). This individual risk is distributed over the whole insured population. Within Social insurance redistribution is not only performed between generations152 (mainly in pension insurance), between healthy and ill (primarily in health- and accident insurance) but also between insured with high income and insured with low income. Especially benefits in kind are strongly redistributed in favour of the poor insured.153 Insured receive benefits in kind independently of the height of their insurance contributions (horizontal equity154) meaning that insured paying higher contributions pay relatively more for services. Cash benefits are calculated on the basis of income because they are supposed to have an incomesubstitution effect in case of illness of the insured. Cash benefits are also limited to the earnings limit of chargeable contributions.155 Further statistics on tax payments and income inequality are provided in Appendix 3. The Austrian Institute for Economic Research reported that redistribution in Austria is primarily achieved by state expenditures (Staatsausgaben).156 State activities cause a considerable redistribution from the higher income levels to the lower income levels. In the early 1990s taxes and public transfers reduced the extent of inequality by 30%.157 In a study published in 2003 Biffl analysed among other topics the distribution of transfer payments.158 She states that the distribution of transfer payments has shifted in favour of the low wage earners. Between 1983 and 1999 the share of social transfers supporting the lowest third of all income groups increased from 150 Hofmarcher, M., Röhrling, G. (2003). ″What are the effects of new user charges in Austria?.″ MIMEO, pp. 1-10 Individuals receiving income support (net income for single persons<690,00 €, for married or cohabitating couples < 1.055,99 €), Recipients of income support in addition to a pension from pension insurance, recipients of a supplementary allowance ( Ergänzungszulage), Persons who can provide evidence for above-average expenditures related to disease or ailment and whose monthly net income does not surpass € 793,50 (singles) or € 1,214.39 for married or cohabitating couples. For each child liable for support these sums are increased by € 72.32. 152 The so called generation contract 153 Tomandl, T. (2005). What you always wanted to know about Social Insurance. Vienna, Manz. 154 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 155 Brodil, W., Windisch-Graetz, M. (2005). Main features of Social Law. Vienna, WUV Universitätsverlag. 156 Guger et al. (1996). ″Distribution effect of public households.″, WIFO in Mayrhuber, C. (2005). Aspects of tax burdens and tax equity in Austria. presentation at the opening event for the ATTAC campaign "Fair Taxes – More for all" May 19 2005 157 Guger 1996 in Guger, A., Marterbauer, M. (2004). ″ The long term development of income distribution in Austria.″ WIFO, pp. 254-276, accessed at http://www.bmsg.gv.at/cms/site/attachments/9/2/3/CH0338/CMS1064227005975/12_einkommen.pdf, on 15.06.06, p. 274 158 Biffl G. (2004). Health and Employment Status. The Case of Austria. WIFO Working Papers 219, pp. 1-25 151 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 52 24.5% to 30.6%. The share of transfer payments benefiting the middle income groups has remained fairly stable; the share for the higher income groups has experienced a significant decrease. In 1999 on average about 33% of the household income of the total population resulted from transfer benefits. Table 2.15 Development of income in Austria Redistribution by the state (1991) Lower Gross income Taxes & contributions State expenditure Health care Eduction 12 9 29 28 16 Middle Upper third of income (dependent households) 28 60 27 64 31 40 34 38 37 47 Sources: Marterbauer, M., Development of incomes in Austria, presentation given at the enquete „Income and sex: strategies for more income equality in Austria, 11 July 2005, Renner Institute, Vienna, documentation of the enquete accessible at: http://www.renner-institut.at/download/texte/einkommen_geschlecht.pdf, accessed 18/0672006 According to Marterbauer there is no recent data available on the redistributive function of the public sector; the data is unsatisfactory. Table 2.15 displays the income and contributions of employed households of the lower, middle and upper thirds of income. While individuals in the lower third of income contribute 12% to total national income, they pay only 9% of total income taxes. On the other hand, individuals in the highest income group contribute 60% of national income and 64% of total income taxes. Thus, in general every person pays proportionally to their income and wage tax and income tax are largely progressive. The state does not redistribute by means of the state income but of the state expenditure. The lower third pays 9% of all state income but receives 29% of all state expenditure. Redistribution is primarily achieved by transfer payments of the state (social spending in health care). Income distribution in Austria depicts a trend towards inequality. Redistribution towards lower levels should be pursued due to motives of equality, for macroeconomic reasons and to encourage private consumption.159 159 Marterbauer, M., Einkommensentwicklung in Österreich, Vortrag im Rahmen der Enquete „Einkommen und Geschlecht: Strategien für mehr Einkommensgerechtigkeit in Österreich, 11. Juli 2005, Renner Institut, Wien, Dokumentation der Enquete abrufbar unter: http://www.renner-institut.at/download/texte/einkommen_geschlecht.pdf, Zugriff am 18.06.06 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 53 3. ACCESS TO HEALTH CARE SERVICES European governments are concerned with pursuing the efficient delivery of high quality health services to the population and also ensuring these services are equitably distributed. Equitable access to health care, or access based on need and not willingness or ability to pay, is an often stated goal of publicly-funded health systems. The precondition of access to care is coverage by health insurance. Indeed, universal, or near universal, coverage of the population by the statutory for a comprehensive basket of health services has been achieved in all European countries. However, even when near universal coverage is achieved, there still may be barriers to access that deter or prevent individuals from seeking care. Access to care is also contingent upon financial factors, such as the degree of cost sharing in the system. In much of Europe, many health care services are free at the point of use, and in those countries that do rely on cost sharing arrangements, extensive protection mechanisms are in place in order to reduce or remove the financial burden from those not, or less, able to pay. Organizational factors such as waiting times, and geographical factors including the distribution of services and individuals’ mobility also impact accessibility of health care. It is important also to recognize the role of personal factors that influence an individuals’ propensity to seek health care. Among the personal factors that may facilitate or hinder access to care include educational attainment, awareness of available services, knowledge of and ability to articulate one’s symptoms, and cultural influences. Knowledge limitations can affect some population groups where eligibility to receive health care requires participation in an administrative procedure or some other form of conditionality. In Austria for example, unemployed people may be unaware that coverage by the public system relates directly to their appearance at a job centre, and failure to appear will lead also to a failure to be eligible to receive care. These types of problem appear to be limited to health systems funded mainly by social health insurance, and in particular to those where entitlement may be automatic but eligibility to receive care depends upon fulfilling certain administrative requirements. In light of the objective to ensure equity in access to health care, international organizations, national governments and researchers have made efforts to measure the extent to which this is achieved. On the one hand, research has focused on analysing the existence of barriers to access, in particular to identify whether these barriers differ across population groups (geographical, ethnic, or, most commonly, socio-economic groups), and on the other hand, researchers have attempted to measure the degree to which utilization of health care services is based on need for health care. Regarding the latter, the extent to which equal utilization for equal need is an appropriate definition of equity is debatable , however, it can be argued that evidence of a disproportionate distribution of utilization favouring certain population groups, such as higher income earners, indicates that the goal equity may be violated. Using as a yardstick of equity the degree of inequality in utilization after standardizing for need differences, studies have revealed that even among countries with universal coverage and largely publicly funded health system, inequity exists. Specifically, while there is little evidence of inequity in GP visits in most countries, or the distribution of GP visits is pro-poor, there is evidence of significant pro-rich inequity in use of specialist care in most countries.160 160 C Masseria, X Koolman, and E van Doorslaer, "Income-Related Inequality in the Probability of a Hospital Admission in Europe," (Ecuity Project 3: Working Paper No. 13, 2004), E van Doorslaer, X Koolman, and A Jones, "Explaining Income-Related Inequalities in Doctor Utilization in Europe," Health Economics 13, no. 7 (2004), E van Doorslaer and C Masseria, "Income-Related Inequality in the Use of Medical Care in 21 OECD Countries," (Paris: OECD, 2004). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 54 3.1 Analysis of European Community Household Panel This section will present results from an international comparison of horizontal equity: the degree of inequality in use is measured by income, after standardising for (measurable) need differences. Inequity is measured using concentration indices of need-standardized distributions for total doctor visits and separately for general practitioner and medical specialist visits, inpatient care and dentist visits in 21 OECD countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Mexico, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Sweden, Spain, Switzerland, the UK and the USA. Physician visits There are important differences between countries in rates of doctor visits. On average, more than 70% of the adult population visited a doctor in the last year; this proportion is lower in Greece (63%), the US (68%), and especially in Mexico (21% only). The proportion visiting a GP is fairly stable at around 7080%, except in Greece and Switzerland, while there is much more variation in specialist visits. The percentage of people visiting a specialist ranges from 20% in Ireland or 30% in Denmark and Norway to 60% in Austria and France. In high-use countries like Germany, Hungary, France, Belgium and Austria the frequency of visits is around 7-8 doctors’ visits per year, which is twice the rate in low-use countries like Finland, Switzerland, or Denmark. These cross-country differences in utilization rates are not correlated with doctor/population ratios. However, differences in remuneration types and cultural differences in seeking medical advice might partly contribute to these differences. When considering within-country variations in use by income, in virtually every OECD country, lowincome groups are more intensive users of doctor services than higher income groups. The differences vary by country but, on average, the bottom income quintiles report about 50% more doctor visits per year than the top income quintiles. However, the probability of doctor visits is higher among richer groups after standardizing for population need (as indicated by positive HI161 index for most countries). The HI indices are significantly different from zero (indicating inequality) in Finland, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, and Sweden. No violation of the horizontal equity principle (i.e. the HI is not significantly different from zero) is found in Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Spain, and the UK. This means that in about half of the countries studied, given the same need, the rich are more likely to see a doctor than the poor. The level of income-related inequity in total number of doctor visits seems to be less pro-rich than when the probability of a doctor visit is measured (Figure 3.1). Pro-rich inequity was found to be statistically significant only in Finland, Portugal, Sweden and Austria, while the reverse is seen in Belgium and Ireland (pro-poor). The probability of contacting a GP is fairly equitably distributed by income, with a few pro-rich exceptions (Finland, and Portugal). Pro-poor inequalities occur in countries where the access to a medical specialist is direct (i.e. Greece, Spain and Germany where there is no gate-keeping systems). But, on the whole, the likelihood of seeing a GP appears distributed according to need, and is not influenced by income. The need-standardized distributions of total GP visits (Figure 3.1) are significantly pro-poor in ten countries. In only one country, Finland there is pro-rich inequity (see further discussion of this result below). Therefore, given that the probability of seeking GP care is equitably distributed, most of the propoor distributional pattern in mean visits must be due to the pro-poor conditional use. In almost every OECD country, the probability of seeing a GP is fairly equally distributed across income, but once people go, the poor are more likely to consult more often. 161 HI is defined as the difference between the degree of income-related inequality in actual health care use and the incomerelated inequality in need-expected use. Horizontal inequity is pro-rich and favours the better-off when the horizontal inequity index, HI, is positive and pro-poor when negative. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 55 The pattern is very different for specialist visits; in all countries, the better-off have a significant higher probability of visiting a specialist. Although there are important differences between countries in the degree to which this occurs, access to specialist services seems not equally distributed across income groups. In all countries, controlling for need, the rich are more likely to seek specialist care than the poor, and especially, but not only, in countries that offer options to seek private care like Finland, Portugal, Ireland, Italy and Spain. Indeed, pro-rich inequity in specialist visits was observed also in countries without such private options, and with GP gatekeepers, like Denmark, Norway, Sweden, and to a less extent also in the Netherlands and the UK. Figure 3.1 Horizontal inequity indices for annual probability of a doctor visit, 21 OECD countries Horizontal Inequity indices for annual probability of a visit 0.14 0.12 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 -0.02 doc vis GP vis U S It al y N or w ay Ca na d Sw a ed en Po rt ug al Fi nl an d M ex ic o U Au K st ra lia Sp ai n G re ec e H un ga ry Au st ria Fr an ce G er m N a et he ny rla nd s Ir el an d D en m ar Be k l Sw giu itz m er la nd -0.04 spec vis Notes: Countries ranked by HI for doctor visits. HI indices are estimated concentration indices for need-standardized use. Positive (negative) index indicates pro-rich (pro-poor) distribution. Source: Van Doorslaer, Masseria, and Koolman 2005. The level of pro-rich inequity is even higher when the total number of specialist visits is measured. Therefore, in this case, the conditional use reinforces the pro-rich patterns induced by the inequitable probability distribution. In virtually all countries, distributions are significantly in favour of the higher income groups. The only exceptions are Norway, the Netherlands and the UK, where the HI indices are positive but not significantly different from zero. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 56 Figure 3.2 Horizontal inequity indices for annual mean number of visits, 19 OECD countries H or iz onta l Ine quity indic es f or annua l number o f v is its 0 .2 5 0 .2 0 0 .1 5 0 .1 0 0 .0 5 0 .0 0 -0 .0 5 do c vis GP vis U Po S rt ug al Fin la nd an ce Au st r ia Sw ed en Fr It a D e ly nm ar k Ca na da Gr ee ce N or w ay Ge rm an y Sp a itz in er la nd H un ga ry Sw Ne th er la nd s nd gi um Be l U Ir el a K -0 .1 0 sp ec vis Notes: Countries ranked by HI index for doctor visits. HI indices are estimated concentration indices for needstandardized use. Positive (negative) index indicates pro-rich (pro-poor) distribution. German GP and specialist indices for ECHP 1996. Source: Van Doorslaer, Masseria, and Koolman 2005. Inpatient care The probability of being admitted to hospital varies across OECD countries and in Europe it ranges from 5% in Greece to 14% in Austria (Van Doorslaer et al. 2004). Distributional patterns are different for the number of nights spent in hospitals; among the European countries those with the lowest average numbers of nights spent in hospitals are Portugal (0.63) and Greece (0.66), while those with the largest are Hungary (2.5) and Austria (2.01). People at the bottom end of the income distribution are more likely to be admitted to hospitals in almost all OECD countries and to spend more nights in hospitals. Unfortunately data on the number of separate admissions are not included in this survey. The picture is more heterogeneous after standardizing for population’s needs (i.e. inequity) (Figure 3.3). For the majority of countries it was impossible to detect any inequity both in the probability and the total number of nights spent in hospitals. This might be due to the very skewed distributions of hospitals care (i.e. many people did not go to hospitals) and the difficulty of explaining length of stay with the information available in these surveys. Significant inequality was found only for the countries with large sample sizes. Individuals with higher income were more likely to be admitted to hospitals in Mexico and Portugal. On the contrary, pro-poor inequity was found in Australia, Canada, Switzerland and the USA. Different results have been found by Masseria, van Doorslaer and Koolman (2004) by pooling several waves of the European Community Household panel Survey (from 1994 to 1998) for 12 European countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Italy, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, the Netherlands, Portugal, LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 57 Spain, and the UK.162 In almost all these countries, the index of horizontal inequity for the probability of hospital admission is positive, indicating income-related inequity in favour of the better-off. The level of inequity is particularly large in Portugal, Greece, Italy, Austria, and Ireland. All these countries, except Austria, offer hospital physicians some way to practise privately alongside the public sector. Belgium is the only country with a negative and statistically significant index, indicating horizontal inequity favouring the poor. This analysis does not separate elective from emergency surgery, which may have different levels of inequity. Figure 3.3 Horizontal inequity index for the probability of hospital admission in 12 European countries (1994-1998) 0.12 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 -0.02 BE NL UK DK ES FR DE IE IT AT EL PT -0.04 -0.06 Source: European Community Household Panel Understanding the sources of inequity Education is an important socioeconomic factor that is related to both income and health. Indeed, differences in medical care use by level of education often reflect the utilization patterns by income. The higher educated, ceteris paribus, are more inclined to visit specialists almost everywhere and particularly so in Hungary where the contribution163 of education to the pro-rich inequity in specialist visits is larger than the contribution of income (Figure 3.4). The picture is less clear-cut with respect to GP visits, total doctor visits and hospital care use; contributions are smaller, and most often negative. This means that education appears to be a more important cause of inequality in specialist care than in other health care services. 162 Finland was excluded because data were available only for two years; for Austria data were available only from the second year (1995); for Germany and the UK comparable data were available only for the first three years 163 The contribution of each variable to total inequality in specialist visits depends on three factors: (1) the importance of this variable (as indicated by its mean), (2) the extent to which it is distributed across income (as indicated by its concentration index value), and (3) the (marginal) effect of this variable on the number of specialist visits (as indicated by the regression coefficient). A positive (negative) contribution increases (decreases) the overall level of inequity. For example, in Hungary the contribution of education is 0.03, and this means that the inequality in specialist use is 0.03 higher than it would have been if education did not have an effect on use. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 58 Figure 3.4 Contribution of socio-economic factors to the overall level of inequity in specialist visits in Europe US UK Switzerland Sweden Spain Portugal Norway Netherlands Income Education Activity status Region Insurance CMU/mcard urban Mexico Italy Ireland Hungary Greece Germany France Finland Denmark Canada Belgium Austria Australia -0.03 0.00 0.03 0.06 0.09 0.12 contribution to inequity Source: Van Doorslaer, Masseria, and Koolman 2005. Differences in employment status might also affect access to medical care, for example by impacting the time costs of using the health system. Ceteris paribus, not being in paid employment seems to influence the degree to which utilization patterns vary by income, and its contribution is generally negative. Individuals receiving a retirement or a disability pension, holding everything else constant (e.g. self-reported health and age), have lower incomes and are less healthy than their working counterparts. Activity status might, therefore, operate as (imperfect) need proxies. However, the difference between needed use and actual use distributions might be driven by the different time costs that people out of work face in comparison with their counterparts. The impact of activity status on inequalities varies across countries. In Denmark and Hungary, the pro-poor contribution to inequity of employment status is driven by the retired; the (early) retired in these countries are worse off than those in the same age category who continue working, and also seek more medical care. In Finland, the pro-rich inequity in GP care is caused by the higher utilization rates of employed versus nonemployed; and this is partly due to the inclusion of occupation-based health visits164, among general primary health care. To understand and interpret the contributions of education and activity status across the countries, a thorough understanding of health care policies, and also labour markets and social policies in each of the countries is necessary. The results of the decomposition analysis for Austria are the following. For GP visits, the only positive contribution to the level of inequity is from income, whereas the remaining factors (age, health status, education and employment) contribute negatively, thus lowering the level of pro-rich inequity. The main contributors to the pro-rich inequity in specialist care are income and education, with health status and age 164 A more meaningful disaggregation of doctor visits in Finland by sector reveals a high degree of pro-rich inequity for occupational care and private visits, a very low degree of pro-rich inequity in outpatient care visits and a pro-poor distribution of health centre contacts (Unto Häkkinen, personal communication). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 59 contributing negatively, and no significant contribution from activity status. Finally for hospital care, the only positive contribution to inequity is income, the remainder exerting a negative influence on equity. 3.2 Analysis of SHARE survey – equity in use of services among over 50 population in Europe Using a new survey – Survey on Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe – perceived barriers to access, waiting times, and income-related inequality in use of physician and hospital services was investigated among the over 50 population in ten European countries, including Austria. Measurement of annual physician and inpatient utilization was based on the following questions: • • • • Have you visited or talked to a ‘medical doctor’ about your health in the past 12 months? How many of these contacts were with a general practitioner or with a doctor at your health care center? During the last twelve months, have you consulted any of the specialists mentioned on card 12165? During the last twelve months, have you been in a hospital overnight? Please consider stays in medical, surgical, psychiatric or in any other specialized wards. Table 3.1 outlines the frequency of health care use among the populations studied. On average the vast majority of the population in each country had reported a visit to a physician, ranging from 78% in Sweden to over 90% in France and Germany; a broader range is seen with just GP visits, from 65-66% in Greece and Sweden to about 89% in France. Regarding specialist visits, the probability of a visit ranged from 20% in Denmark to 57% in Germany. Therefore, it appears individuals are making relatively more use of physician services in France and Germany with lower rates in Sweden and Greece. The proportion of the population reporting an inpatient stay of at least one night is considerably lower, ranging from about 9% of the population in Greece and the Netherlands, to 20% in Austria. If the overall use of health care –medical visits and inpatient admission – is taken into consideration, it appears that some countries such as the Netherlands and Greece use proportionally less health care than others whereas France and Germany have the highest users of health services. Table 3.1 Sample sizes and proportion of the population reporting health care visits Country % reporting % reporting % reporting % reporting any medical GP visit specialist visit inpatient stay visit (at least one night) Austria 85.74 81.27 39.40 19.99 France 93.58 89.02 49.16 15.07 Denmark 81.48 78.41 20.65 12.62 Germany 92.59 85.94 57.06 15.98 Greece 79.66 65.01 36.99 8.76 Italy 83.77 78.23 43.59 12.46 Netherlands 81.26 75.43 40.91 9.11 Spain 88.87 83.78 45.08 11.22 Sweden 77.58 65.70 36.01 11.81 Switzerland 84.53 76.63 35.89 11.79 Source: Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe 165 Card 12 includes the following specialists: specialist for heart disease, pulmonary, gastroenterology, diabetes or endocrine diseases; dermatologist; neurologist; opthalmologist; ear, nose and throat specialist; rheumatologist or physiatrist; orthopaedist; surgeon; psychiatrist; gynaecologist; urologist; oncologist; and geriatrician. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 60 Small barriers to access health care for older people are evident everywhere. More than 3% of the survey respondents declared to forgo health care either because of costs or because services were unavailable (Table 3.2). The proportion of individuals declaring to forgo care is more than 6% in Italy, France, Germany and Sweden and reaches over 10% in Greece. Although it was impossible to identify an age pattern, in almost all countries people with worse health status were more likely to forgo health care (Figure 3.5). Table 3.2 Percentage of people who declared to forgo health care Country Forgo Forgo Total because of because care percentage costs unavailable declared to forgo Austria 2.89 0.74 3.63 Denmark 1.44 1.88 3.32 France 6.18 2.28 8.46 Germany 5.42 1.47 6.89 Greece 5.64 4.87 10.51 Italy 5.10 3.48 8.58 Netherlands 2.01 0.53 2.54 Spain 3.02 1.86 4.88 Sweden 2.83 3.33 6.16 Switzerland 3.68 0.74 4.42 Source: Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe Cost-sharing may be a major barrier for accessing health care. Figure 3.6 depicts the proportion of people who declared they had to pay part of the inpatient costs, and if they had to pay more than 100 Euros. In Sweden, almost all citizens had to pay partly of inpatient costs (98.5%), although only 25% had to pay more than 100 euros. Cost-sharing is also widely used for rationing health care use in Switzerland, Germany, Austria and Greece (and in Greece informal payments represent the highest proportion of personal costs). Figure 3.5 Proportion of people who declared to forgo health care by self- assessed health 30 25 very good good fair very poor poor 20 15 10 5 i tz er la nd Sw Sp ai n ed en Sw N et he rl a nd s Ita ly re ec e G an y er m G en m ar k D Fr an ce Au st ria 0 Source: Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 61 Figure 3.6 Proportion of people who paid part of the costs of inpatient care 120 cost-sharing yes > 100 euros 100 80 60 40 20 nd n er la it z Sw ai n Sp ed e Sw N et he r la nd s It a ly ce G re e m an y G er D en m ar k e nc Fr a Au st ri a 0 Source: Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe Are higher income individuals more likely to have had contact with a physician or hospital than lower income individuals, once need (as measured by multiple health status indicators) is standardized for?166 It appears that the there is significantly pro-rich income-related inequity in the probability of doctor visit in Italy, Germany, Austria, the Netherlands, Sweden and Switzerland (See Figure 3.7). When examining GP and specialist visits separately, some important differences are revealed. The analysis of GP visits reveals little evidence of inequity; after standardizing for differences in need, there is evidence of pro-rich incomerelated inequity in Netherlands, Italy, Sweden and Switzerland but no significant inequity in the remaining countries (See Figure 3.8). The results are quite different when looking at specialist visits. In all countries but the Netherlands we found statistically significant pro-rich inequity in the likelihood of contacting a specialist (See Figure 3.9). Regarding inpatient care, in almost all countries, the index of horizontal inequity, defined as the difference between the distributions of use and need, shows little violation of equity (see Figure 3.10). However, the distribution of inpatient visit probability is significantly pro-rich in Greece and Switzerland. Unfortunately data on the number of separate hospital admissions is not available. 166 For any physician visit, GP, specialist, and inpatient care, we modeled the probability of a visit using multivariate logistic regression on the full set of explanatory variables. In order to achieve horizontal equity in inpatient care, resources ought to be allocated according to needs, irrespective of personal characteristics unrelated to needs, such as income, wealth, and education (Van Doorslaer, Wagstaff and Rutten, 1993).The level of horizontal inequity in the access to health care was calculated according to methodology developed by Wagstaff and van Doorslaer and the focus is mainly on income-related inequity although the results of the other two indexes are also described. The horizontal inequity index is defined as the difference between the degree of incomerelated inequality in actual health care use and the income-related inequality in need-expected use. The latter is obtained as the predicted admission probabilities from a regression on need indicators. A zero inequity index implies that, after controlling for differences in need across income groups, all individuals have equal probability of using health services, regardless of income. After adjusting for need, when service use is more concentrated among the better-off, the horizontal inequity index is positive, and a negative index indicates pro-poor inequity. The former implies that individuals on higher income are more like to visit a physician than one would expect on the basis of their reported need. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 62 Figure 3.7 Income-related inequity in probability of any physician visit in the over 50 population 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 nd n Sw it z Sw er la ed e s N Au et he rla nd st ri a an y G er m It a ly e ec en m G re ar k e nc D -0.01 Fr a Sp ai n 0 -0.02 Source: Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe Figure 3.8 Income-related inequity in probability of GP visit in the over 50 population 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 nd n er la it z Sw It a ly ed e Sw N et he r la nd s st ri a Au m an y G er D en m ar k nc e Fr a Sp -0.01 ai n 0 -0.02 -0.03 Source: Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 63 Figure 3.9 Income-related inequity in probability of a specialist visit in the over 50 population 0.16 0.14 0.12 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 Sw k D en m ar nd it z er la It a ly e nc Fr a m an y G er n ed e Sw st ri a Au N et he r Sp la nd s -0.02 ai n 0 Source: Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe Figure 3.10 Income-related inequity in probability of an inpatient stay in the over 50 population 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 itz G re ec e er la nd k ar en m D ed en Sw Sp ai n an y Ita ly a Au st ri G er m Sw -0.1 N et he rla nd s Fr a -0.05 nc e 0 Source: Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe In summary, there is evidence of pro-rich inequity in the probability of visiting a GP in the Netherlands, Italy, Sweden and Switzerland; for specialist visit in all countries but the Netherlands and for inpatient care in Greece and Switzerland. While some of the inequity may be explained by differences in waiting times, cost sharing arrangements and accessibility of voluntary health insurance, it is important to further investigate the potential contributors of inequality in health care use among older people in Europe. Comparing the results of equity analyses using two different surveys and different age groups reveal broad similarities. In Austria, the probability of visiting any doctor, and specifically a specialist is pro-rich in both studies, whereas there is no inequity for GP visits. The difference is seen in hospital visits, where the probability of admission appears to be pro-rich using pooled European Community Household Survey data, while there is no inequity found using the Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe. This difference could be a result of the significantly smaller sample size in SHARE. Both surveys did reveal high LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 64 utilization rates for hospital care, with both studies showing Austria with the highest proportion of the sample reporting at least one night in hospital. 3.3 Access to care and cost sharing One possible explanation for the presence of inequity in some countries could be the cost sharing arrangements. The income-related inequity that is seen in physician care could arise from either user charges for physician visits, or even from cost sharing with pharmaceuticals. User charges for physician visits are present in Austria, France, Greece, Italy, Sweden and Switzerland. In Sweden, the median user charge for physician visit is around 100 SEK, with an out-of-pocket maximum of 900 SEK per year including both physician and inpatient user charges.167 Indeed, the countries that impose cost-sharing for physician visits are also those with the highest levels of pro-rich inequity. In addition to formal cost sharing, informal payments are quite prevalent in Greece, which may be playing a part in explaining the income-related inequity found for physician visits in that country. The combination of formal and informal payments for health care services may be the reason behind the relatively high proportion of individuals reporting to have foregone health care because of costs (over 6%) in particular among those with poor or very poor health conditions. Costs for pharmaceuticals may also deter individuals from seeking physician care because of the ‘bundling’ of physician services with prescription drugs in some countries.168 In Austria and Germany there is a flat copayment per item (between €4 and €5) for which pensioners on income subsidies and individuals on social assistance are exempt in Austria, and general ceilings are offered in Germany. Co-insurance for pharmaceuticals is used in Denmark, France and Greece, although there are various protection mechanisms in place such as reduced rates are given for individuals suffering from chronic conditions.169 In Italy and Spain, individuals over aged 60 (65 in Spain) are exempt from co-payment and co-insurance payments for pharmaceuticals. In Sweden, individuals must bear the full financial burden of prescription drug costs although the maximum amount that must be paid in full is 900 SEK, and for costs between 900 and 1800 SEK, the costs are partially subsidised (except for insulin for diabetes, which is never charged). It is less likely that user charges would deter individuals from seeking inpatient care, although it is possible, in particular for elective surgery. In Austria and Germany, there is a co-payment per day around €8-9, with exemptions after 14 days in Germany and 28 days in Austria170. In Sweden there is a co-payment of 80 SEK per night (about €8.5) (up to the maximum of 900 SEK combined including physician user charges). However, inequity in inpatient care was not found in the countries that impose charges for inpatient services. 3.4 Access to care and voluntary health insurance Another factor impacting the potential financial barriers to access is whether or not the individual is covered by VHI that may allow faster access to care, or access to better quality services. Barriers to access to supplementary VHI are high. In all supplementary VHI systems access is on the basis of willingness and ability to pay, and pricing is on the basis of risk factors such as gender and age. Moreover, cover is usually not extended to pre-existing conditions. Because primary cover is provided by the public system (or by 167 Thomson, Mossialos, and Jemiai, "Cost Sharing for Health Services in the European Union." C.H Tuohy, C.M. Flood, and M Stabile, "How Does Private Finance Affect Public Health Care Systems? Marshaling the Evidence from OECD Nations," J Health Polit Policy Law 29, no. 3 (2004). 169 Thomson, Mossialos, and Jemiai, "Cost Sharing for Health Services in the European Union." 170 Ibid. 168 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 65 substitutive VHI where it exists) governments have not sought to intervene in markets for supplementary VHI to facilitate access for those unable to pay (the poor and those at high risk of incurring a loss). In the case of France, complementary VHI covers the costs of co-payments. The finding from the analysis of SHARE data that individuals who were covered by VHI in France were almost four times as likely to have visited a physician in the past year could be explained in part by the removal of a financial barrier for these people. In the case of Germany, higher income earners (with annual incomes over €40,000) are permitted to opt-out of the statutory health insurance system and to purchase substitutive VHI (and in general about 7% of the population do opt out, representing less than a quarter of those who are eligible).171 The finding that individuals with VHI were significantly more likely to have visited a specialist or had an inpatient stay may be a reflection of the better access afforded to individuals with private alternatives to the public system. 3.5 Access to care for asylum seekers, refugees and illegal immigrants As legal residents in most countries, asylum seekers and refugees have publicly-financed access to health care, although not necessarily within the general public system. The Treaty of Amsterdam of 1999 assigned competence for asylum and migration policy to the European Community; and following, the 2003 Council Directive “Laying Down Minimum Standards for the Reception of Asylum Seekers” was passed. This attempts to harmonize conditions for asylum seekers in schooling, employment and health care, such that applicants shall “receive the necessary health care which shall include, at least, emergency care and essential treatment of illness”. Therefore, beyond emergency care there is variation across Member States in access to other forms of care.172 On the other hand, illegal immigrants are covered in some countries, but not in others. In those where they are covered they may nevertheless fail to seek or to access care; in those where they are not covered, they may be able to gain de facto access to care within the public system or through informal, charitable provision. They will also be able to access emergency care and, in some countries, care for certain named conditions (for example, infectious diseases).173 In England the entitlement rules that apply to persons ordinarily resident apply equally to asylum seekers and to those with refugee status (asylum seekers who have been successful in their application). They also apply to asylum seekers who are in the process of appealing a negative decision on their application to remain in the country. Thus asylum seekers receive free NHS treatment and are subject to the same statutory charges and conditions for exemption from charge as persons ordinarily resident. Failed asylum seekers awaiting deportation from the UK and other illegal immigrants are not eligible for free NHS treatment, and are subject to the regulations governing overseas visitors’ access to NHS care. Asylum seekers in Austria are included in the statutory health insurance scheme if they receive no health cover under other legal provisions, and their contributions are paid by the Federal Government. About 4.5% of asylum seekers remain without health care cover, which may largely be attributed to the administrative barriers relating to entitlement, specifically that require asylum seekers to be assigned residence in a federal state before leaving the reception centre, and to remain there, otherwise cover will be forfeited.174 171 Mossialos and Thomson, Voluntary Health Insurance in the European Union. T Foubister and M Worz, "Access to Health Care: Illegal Immigrants and Asylum Seekers," Euro Observer 8, no. 2 (2006). 173 Ibid. 174 M Norredam, A Mygind, and A Krasnik, "Access to Health Care for Asylum Seekers in the European Union: A Comparative Study of Country Policies," European Journal of Public Health 16, no. 3 (2006). 172 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 66 In Germany, asylum seekers are not insured through the public coverage system but are covered instead through a separate scheme for asylum seekers. Illegal immigrants, by law, have the same access rights as asylum seekers, but in practice fail to exercise these rights for fear of disclosure of their status – they are forced to rely, therefore, on informal provision. In Belgium, illegal immigrants, in contrast, have no coverage and only have access to emergency care. Ireland provides cover for asylum seekers as Category 1 (i.e. low income) medical card holders, but barriers to access nevertheless remain. Italy provides cover for asylum seekers through the NHS. Cover is extended to illegal immigrants during pregnancy and for six months after the birth of the child. In Italy illegal immigrants are also entitled to emergency care and to care for a list of named services. 3.6 Geographical access to care Availability of health care resources is a prerequisite for achieving equal access across the population. There is no clear pattern between western and CEE countries in the number of hospitals and hospital beds per 100,000 inhabitants (Table 3.3). The number of hospitals per 100,000 ranges from 0.9 in Sweden to 16.7 in Cyprus, and the number of beds from 255 in Turkey to 892 in Germany. The number of hospitals and hospital beds are larger among the new Member States than in the EU-15, consistent with the literature indicating an oversupply of health care resources in this region. In addition to limited supply of health care resources, geographical distance to hospital might be a barrier in fulfilling the goal of universal access to health care. In the EU-15 more than 50% of citizens live close to hospitals (the distance can be covered in less than 20 minutes either by car, public transport or foot). The proportion lowers somewhat for the new Member States and three Candidate Countries, where 38% of citizens have easy access to hospitals175. Citizens of the EU-15 are more likely to reach hospitals by using either their cars or public transport, whereas in the new Member States and candidate countries it is more common to bridge distances by foot. Table 3.3 Number of hospital and hospital beds per 100 000 inhabitants in Europe in 2003 or the latest available year Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Luxembourg Netherlands Portugal Spain Sweden UK Cyprus Hospital beds per 100 000 Hospitals per 100 000 834.1 699.0 413.4 724.9 780.1 892.7 471.7 351.5 411.8 676.7 457.7 363.7 360.6 522.0 421.8 436.3 3.4 2.2 1.3 7.3 5.3 4.4 3.1 2.5 2.2 8.4 1.2 2.1 1.9 0.9 2.7 16.7 175 J Alber and U Kohler, "Quality of Life in Europe," (Dublin: Health and care in an enlarged Europe European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions, 2004). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 67 Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Lithuania Latvia Malta Poland Slovakia Slovenia Bulgaria Romania Turkey EU-15 NMC CC3 855.5 595.3 783.5 868.2 781.4 482.2 557.1 732.3 495.6 628.5 656.5 255.7 558.8 658.7 513.6 3.6 3.7 1.8 5.6 5.6 2.5 2.2 2.6 1.4 3.8 1.9 1.7 3.3 4.6 2.5 Source: WHO Health for All 2005 When surveyed, it appeared that easy access to primary care is secured for 85% of the EU-15 citizens but only for 62% of the citizens in new Member States and candidate countries. In the EU-15 only in Portugal and Spain more than 30% of the respondents reported to travel more than 20 minutes to reach a primary care facility. In the new Member States and three Candidate Countries the countries with a smaller percentage of citizens that report easy access (< 40%) are Estonia, Turkey, Lithuania and Latvia.176 One wave of the Eurobarometer, a survey with the intention to monitor public opinion in the European Union, asked questions on geographical proximity to health care providers. Figure 3.11 depicts the percentages of the population in the selected European countries who answer that they have access to a hospital in less than 20 minutes.177 Whereas ca. 70% of the population in the Netherlands has access to a hospital within less than 20 minutes only ca. 30% of the population in Hungary has. Overall there seems to be a relation between more people having access to a hospital and population density. Regarding GP access, a large majority of the population in selected countries has access to a GP within 20 minutes (Figure 3.12). 176 Ibid. Moreover Alber & Kohler (2004) provide data for the percentages of the population who lives within walking distance of both hospitals and GPs and also data on rural/urban differences for these two categories, however, only for the newly accessed countries and the Candidate Countries (Bulgaria, Romania and Turkey) – we do not show these data here. 177 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 68 Figure 3.11 Percentage of respondents who report having access to a hospital in less than 20 minutes Austria Belgium France Germany Hungary Ireland Italy Poland the Netherlands United Kingdom 10 New Member States EU 15 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Source: Eurobarometer EB 51.1, Candidate Countries Eurobarometer 2002.1 Figure 3.12 Percentage of respondents who report having access to a GP in less than 20 minutes Austria Belgium France Germany Hungary Ireland Italy Poland the Netherlands United Kingdom 10 New Member States EU 15 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Source: Eurobarometer EB 51.1, Candidate Countries Eurobarometer 2002.1 To achieve equal access to health care, proximity to hospital or primary care should not depend on individual socioeconomic characteristics such as income and economic activity. However, in some countries people with a higher income report easier access to hospitals (Figure 3.13). The accessibility gap in the EU-15 between the highest and lowest income quartile is higher than 20% in Belgium, France, Italy, LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 69 Portugal and the UK; in the new Member States only Czech Republic, Slovenia, Estonia, Lithuania, and Latvia the difference is less than 20%, but in Hungary and Slovakia is even larger than 30%. Lighter blue bars signify new member states, dark blue bars represent the original 15 EU member states, and orange signifies acceding/candidate countries: Bulgaria, Romania and Turkey. It appears that in Austria the lowest income groups are more proximate to GPs, however, the reverse is seen in most other countries (Figure 3.14). 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 IT M T TR HU SK PT UK PL BE CY RO FR EE SL LV BG FI IE EL DE NL SI AT ES 0 LU DK LT CZ Difference between lowest and highest quintile Figure 3.13 Difference between the lowest and highest income quintile in perceived distance to hospital Source: Eurobarometer 2002 For proximity to general practitioners the level of income-related inequalities is lower in all countries. The average difference between the lowest and highest income quartile is 2.7% in the EU-15, and 11.9% in the new Member States; but large heterogeneity is observed across the EU-15 countries (Figure 19). Individuals with lower income have significantly easier access in Austria (17.9% difference favouring lower income groups), but the reverse is true in Greece (14.9), Finland (14.4), Belgium (13.4%), and the UK (12.3). In the new Member States and the three Candidate Countries, people with higher income live closer to a doctor, in particular in Cyprus (21.2%), Hungary (15.5%), Slovakia (14.6%), and Poland (12.9%). Figure 3.14 Difference between the lowest and highest income quintile in perceived distance to GP 20 15 10 5 FI SK EL HU CY LT UK PL BE TR SI SE RO LV IT CZ M T IE NL DK EE PT BG FR -5 LU DE 0 AT ES Difference between lowest and highest quintile 25 -10 -15 -20 Source: Eurobarometer 2002 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 70 3.7 Barriers to access health services in Austria 3.7.1 Financial barriers Few empirical studies on this topic exist in Austria. The most important ones are a study performed by the OEBIG (Rosian et al. 2003), a study undertaken by the regional sickness fund of Carinthia in 2004 (Wurzer, Robnig and Rodler 2004) and various publications of the Institute of Advanced Studies. Other authors publishing articles related to user charges (and their effects) are Reichmann and Sommersguter-Reichmann (2004) as well as Streissler (2003). Further contributions to the topic can be found in the journal of Austrian social insurance, Soziale Sicherheit. It is difficult to measure the relative burden which user charges represent for the insured because regulations in the different social insurance laws are very heterogeneous. In addition benefit packages and exemptions may vary due to provisions in the sickness funds’ statutes making comparisons even more difficult. An essential requirement for any researcher is to describe the data base used in an empirical study as well as clarifying the definition of user charges employed. Furthermore to state which data is used, (i.e. insured including or excluding dependants). Multiple insured ought to be adjusted for178 and the structure of the insured population (compulsory insured, unemployed, voluntary insured) as well as the age distribution amongst the population analysed should be taken into consideration. A study by Hofmarcher and Röhrling179 looks at the different burden of the following groups of insured due to user charges (prescription charges, medical treatment by office-based physicians and ambulatory care): ASVG insured, B-KUVG insured, insured of the Insurance fund of the Austrian Railway Industry as well as of the Social Insurance Authority for Business (self-employed). The last three groups of insured pay a percentage of treatment costs (usually about 20-30% of the contractual fee) when consulting a physician instead of a quarterly charge– at the time of the study – which was recently changed to a yearly servicecharge for the e-card. Figure 3.15 Changes in co-insurance 1988-2001 Source: Hofmarcher, M., Röhrling, G. (2003). Cost sharing in the EU health care systems: Austria, study commissioned by the EC and the London School of Economics, LSE Health. For the time span analysed the burden for insured according to the ASVG was significantly lower than that of the insured paying a co-payment (percentage of treatment costs). In 2001 the average insured with the ASVG paid €66.2 whereas other insured paid an average of about €153.8. During the period analysed the 178 About 500.000 people in Austria are insured at two sickness funds at the same time (Information of the Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB on 18/04/2006) 179 Hofmarcher, M., Röhrling, G. (2003). Cost sharing in the EU health care systems: Austria, Study commissioned by the EC and the London School of Economics, LSE Health. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 71 average amount of user charges of ASVG insured more than doubled, the average user charges of the insured with a co-payment however increased only by about 50%. This was due to the introduction of the fee for the health insurance voucher as well as the fee for treatment in a hospital’s outpatient department (the first has in the mean time been replaced by a yearly service charge for the e-card and the second has been abolished). The balance sheet of the health insurance funds for the year 2004 displays the following revenues, titled “fees, co-payments for treatment and share of costs” (Gebühren, Behandlungsbeiträge und Kostenteile) in million Euros (Table 3.4). Table 3.4 User charges in Social Insurance (exemplary) 2004 – in million Euros All sickness Prescription Fee for Co-payments Share funds charges insurance for medical costs voucher treatment Revenue in million Euros 512.3 335.2 45.7 79.5 51.9 % 100% 65.43% 8.91% 15.52% 10.14% of Source: Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB It is important to note that user charges in the above table only represent a fraction of the actual user charges paid by patients, especially for the insured of the regional sickness funds. Apart from these numerous indirect user charges exist (user charges for services i.e. benefits which are not reimbursed by social health insurance) and do not figure in the balance sheets of social health insurance funds. These include some dental services, drugs with a price below the prescription charge or many alternative medicines or homoeopathic treatments. The average user charge for each insured (incl. dependants) is given in the table below (structured based on the positions of the balance sheet). Table 3.5 User charges per insured (including dependants) Average user Total Prescription Fee for charges per charges insurance beneficiary voucher Sickness fund CoShare payments costs for medical treatment WGKK 53,77 45,78 7,98 0 0 NÖGKK 53,22 46,21 7,01 0 0 BGKK 54,35 48,20 6,15 0 0 OÖGKK 40,82 33,87 6,95 0 0 STGKK 44,69 37,58 7,11 0 0 KGKK 42,17 35,42 6,75 0 0 SGKK 40,85 33,67 7,19 0 0 TGKK 46,53 38,74 7,79 0 0 VGKK 40,64 33,84 6,80 0 0 BKKs 75,40 70,47 4,93 0 0 VAEB 74,65 71,27 3,39 0 0 VAE 124,87 56,88 0 68,00 0 BVA 137,90 47,45 0 90,45 0 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment of 72 SVAGW 100,00 29,84 0 0 70,16 SVB 67,26 36,71 0 0 30,56 F= highest value, F = second highest value, F = third highest value Sources: User charges: Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB Beneficiaries: Database of beneficiaries of the Hauptverband, insurance relationships (Versicherungsverhältnisse), yearly average 2004 Even though these average values may be interesting it would in order to be able to perform an objective comparison, be necessary to complement the user charges of the dependants (at least adding direct user charges for dental prosthesis or hospital care). Furthermore to adjust for the multiple insured and the age structure of the respective funds. Equally the intensity of services consumed by the patient ought to be taken into consideration. User charges in Austria are not aligned, they are developed and exist in an isolated way meaning that no upper limit exists which considers all user charges (per person per time period) and thus would limit the social burden placed on certain patients. The Union of Salaried Private Sector Employees180 published data according to which in 2001 an insured according to the ASVG paid an average of €181.52 user charges (including fixed dental prosthesis), an insured according to the B-KUVG €194.84, an insured according to the GSVG €139.21 and an insured according to the BSVG €136.95. Maybe the difference to the above shown data can be explained by the different definition of user charges, the one of the Union of Salaried Private Sector Employees being more comprehensive181. Furthermore dependants were not taken as a denominator but only insured. The regional sickness fund of Carinthia182 states in its study on user charges that the average burden of insured related to user charges is very heterogeneous. Insured according to the ASVG pay more than selfemployed or farmers. Insured according to the B-KUVG pay more, but also represent less small-scale enterprises than the group of ASVG insured. On average user charges for insured according to the B-KUVG amounted to €195, those of insured according to the ASVG to €182, those insured according to the GSVG to €139 and those insured to the BSVG to €136. In their study on user charges published in 2003 Hofmarcher and Röhrling used Data of the European Community Household Panel (ECHP) in order to perform their analysis. They show that average payments for user charges in 2000 rise with increasing income, for men and women. Women of each group always pay higher user charges than men, which originates in the fact that they consume more medical services. The highest burden due to user charges is borne by women of the income class €1,382-1,962. The analysis of the ECHP data, comparing average user charges with the level of education shows that women with the lowest level of education consult general practitioners most frequently. Consultations of specialists increase with higher levels of education, for both men and women183. Men with the highest level of education spend on average € 33.4 per year, followed by women with the lowest level of education paying € 30.6. In comparison to their income (mean gross yearly income) women with the lowest level of education spend a twice as big share on user charges as do women with the highest level of education. For men this difference amounts to about a fifth. The study by the regional sickness fund of Carinthia (KGKK) reports that insured women (at the KGKK) in the age interval of 20 to 70 years, pay higher average user charges than men. Insured in the lower income groups pay higher average user charges than those in the higher income groups. 89% of the patients who are exempt from the prescription charge (8% of the insured of the KGKK) belong to the income group earning 180 Klec, G.(2004). User charges in the health care system. GPA, Union of private employees, accessed at: http://www1.gpa.at/gesundheit/index1.htm on 03/11/2005 181 Includes user charges for fixed dental prosthesis, for hospital care, charge for outpatient visits, orthodontic regulations, transportation costs, co-payment for dependants for inpatient care, therapeutic aids and devices, costsharing in integrated institutions of social insurance, treatment by private medical doctors, and spa treatment. 182 Probst, J, User charges – Social and health political contradiction, in Wurzer, A., Robinig, R., Rodler, J. (2004). User charges, a review for orientation. Klagenfurt, Regional sickness fund of Carinthia. 183 Hofmarcher, M., Röhrling, G. (2003). ″What do new user charges in Austria entail? ″ MIMEO, pp. 1-10. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 73 €900 or less a month (81% being pensioners). This group of insured causes, higher expenditures for the sickness fund (for all age groups), confirming a correlation between poverty and illness. Because of their exemption from the prescription charge they are also exempt from other user charges and thus display lower average user charges (for all income groups) than those insured who are not exempt from the prescription charge.184 Elderly people generally utilize more medical services than younger people. They consult physicians more often, consume more medicines and experience more hospital stays. In their study Hofmarcher and Röhrling show that women of the age group 51-65 and men older than 65 consult a physician most frequently. Wurzer et al. state that insured of the age group 71-80 years cause the highest expenses for the regional sickness fund of Carinthia185. Both men and women older than 65 years spend nearly the double amount on user charges compared to men and women in the age group 15-30 years. For elderly people, especially for women older than 65 years, user charges represent a larger share of their income than for younger people. According to a study of the regional sickness fund of Carinthia, average user charges (of expenses) are highest for the age groups 51-60 and 61-70. 9% of all patients belong to the last group, causing 17% of all expenses and paying 18% of all user charges. Highest average user charges apply to patients in the age group of 81-90 and amounts to € 197. Based on a study published by the Union of Salaried Private Sector Employees186 (data basis 1999) user charges of pensioners are disproportionately high. Average user charges of insured according to the ASVG for medical treatment (contract physicians, including dentists) amount to €44.5 for employed and to €67.5 for pensioners. Average user charges for hospital care add up to €36.3 for employed and €155.7 for pensioners. In a WHO survey only 4.7% of the questioned Austrian population stated that they could not afford certain health care during the past year187. In general user charges in Austria are an exception (principle of benefits in kind) and if they exist they are usually not so high as to pose a real barrier to access health care for the insured. Moreover they are always accompanied by exemption mechanisms which are supposed to ensure that they are socially and politically acceptable. The impact of user charges in Austria is partially related to the behaviour of health care providers. If these try to maintain the level of income they had before the introduction of user charges, they will, depending on their reimbursement mechanism, be incentivised to increase the amount of services provided. When the Institute of Advanced Studies developed a model in which they analysed the outcomes of an introduction of a €10.00 fee for physician visits (per visit) they found out that income generated by this measure could, in the short run, eliminate the deficit of the sickness funds, but that it would only be a onetime effect. The adoption of a physician fee would predominantly affect women with low incomes as women (of all income levels) tend to consult physicians more often than men and as especially women with a low income display a high number of GP visits. Equally the elderly population (men and women) would be affected more strongly by such a fee. The willingness to pay user charges is considerably higher for women as for men and rises with the level of education.188 It is clear which groups are affected most by user charges. However it is only partially possible to find out if user charges motivate patients in Austria to adopt more cost-conscious behaviour or if they represent real financial barriers for them, preventing them to access care. Indicators are the temporary reduction in the 184 Wurzer, A., Robinig, R., Rodler, J. (2004). User charges, a review for orientation. Klagenfurt, Regional sickness fund of Carinthia. 185 Wurzer, A., Robinig, R., Rodler, J. (2004). User charges, a review for orientation. Klagenfurt, Regional sickness fund of Carinthia. 186 Klec, G.(2004). User charges in the health care system, GPA, Union of private employees, accessed at http://www1.gpa.at/gesundheit/index1.htm on 03/11/2005 187 Who pays for your health care, accessed at http://www.gewinn.co.at/kredite/content.php?article=888m on 5.01.06 188 Hofmarcher, M., Riedel, M., Röhrling, G. (2005). ″Focus: Physician fee in Austria – how much will they bring and who will pay them?″ Health System Watch I:2005, supplement of the Austrian journal of social insurance Soziale Sicherheit, pp. 7-11 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 74 number of prescriptions after increasing the prescription charge. Due to the fairly low burden resulting from user charges and to the numerous exemptions it is assumed that the proportion of population not accessing care because of financial reasons is very low. More information on user charges can be found in Appendix 4. 3.7.2 Geographical barriers The number and distribution of contract physicians is regulated by the Location Plan which forms part of the general contract negotiated between the Hauptverband, the regional sickness fund and the Medical Chamber of the respective federal state189. By means of the Location Plan insured should be granted a fair (in terms of demand) and efficient provision of care through physicians in private practices. If required, new contract posts are established. Based on § 135 para.2 ASVG the insured should be able to choose from at least two physicians or group practices appropriate for the kind of care required who can be reached within a moderate time. In practice there are significant variations in the provision of medical care in urban and rural areas, whereby the latter partially exhibit a considerably lower level of specialist care. In general emergency care services are provided in line with international standards, with regards to other types of care insured in rural areas may in some cases have to accept longer travelling distances (max. 1.5 hours). Reachability of physicians and execution of choice of medical providers may be compromised for insured living in rural areas (compared to insured living in urban areas). Even in urban areas shortages of specialists arise at certain times as opening hours are not co-ordinated amongst physicians (evenings, weekends and nights). However physicians are available on a standby basis throughout Austria (General Practitioners). For more details on the distribution of health care professionals and facilities, see Chapter 2.9.3. 3.7.3 Cultural barriers The study on “Social inequality and health care190” (commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women) placed a special focus on foreigners and migrants, amongst other groups of individuals. Migrants are more likely to be endangered by poverty (28%) than people who are born in Austria (11%)191. The association between poverty and health care is analysed in more detail in Chapter 8.2.3. Access to health services will, in general be more dependant on the existence of insurance coverage than on the availability of financial means. This is because user charges for the insured population in Austria do not pose a significant barrier to utilising health services. Other barriers (apart from lack in insurance coverage) include language- or cultural barriers (values, beliefs, role models) which are partially combined with limited knowledge on available benefits of social insurance. Foreigners may seek medical advice at a later moment in time thus being at risk of having more severe and chronic sickness spells/illnesses. Legal regulations make it difficult for women following their family relatives by coming to Austria to find work. Burdens related to past experiences (traumatic events such as war, violence, political prosecution) and present life (discrimination, language problems) can result in psychological impacts and damages. Migrant-specific measures to improve access to health care services are described below. 3.7.4 Barriers in accessing preventive health services192 Barriers preventing people from accessing or utilising the health system may be detected in a number of areas. Disability is one such example. In the field of gynaecology disabled women have reported being recommended long term contraceptive methods without first being consulted about their wishes193 and, in 189 Nationwide insurance funds either adopt this Location Plan or use own informal plans Pochobradsky, E., Habl, C., Schleicher, B., Hlava, A. (2002). Social inequality and health care. Study commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. Vienna. 191 Results from the EU-SILC, see Statistics Austria at www.statistik.at 192 Univ.-Prof. Dr. Anita Rieder, Kitty Lawrence BEng. 193 Viennese Women’s health care report (Wiener Frauengesundheitsbericht) unpublished, Austrian Women’s Health Report (Österreichischer Frauengesundheitsbericht) 2005/2006 190 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 75 case of pregnancy, have often been recommended to have an abortion. In a study of gynaecologists the most frequently cited barriers to treatment of disabled women were access to the practice, which is often not suitable for disabled, lack of knowledge with respect to disability, and the time taken up being too great. For the disabled population general barriers to accessing the health system include lack of disabled access in buildings, brochures not produced in braille, lack of knowledge of sign language, problems in dealing with women with psychological illnesses. Although, planning standards for obstacle-free building, which are summarised in the ÖNORM B1600, have been in existence since 1994 they are not mandatory. Within the scope of the 58th ASVG-amendment of August 2001, provision of disabled access was made mandatory for group practices. In this respect it must be noted that barriers to mobility in rural areas restrict disabled women’s lives to a greater extent than in cities and towns. In 2003 the Main Association of Social Insurance Institutions (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger) together with the Austrian Medical Chamber, the Austrian Consortium for Rehabilitation (Österreichische Arbeitsgemeinschaft für Rehabilitation), and the Umbrella Association for the representation of the interests of disabled persons (Dachverband der Vereinigung zur Vertretung der Interessen behinderte Menschen) carried out a survey of the actual situation in doctors practices with regards to ease of access and facilities for disabled persons. Here Vienna was found, in most cases, to be below the Austrian average in terms of obstacle free facilities for the disabled. In November 2003, the Viennese Medical Chamber announced that 12% of all contract practices would be adapted to allow disabled access over the following five years and thereby allow disabled persons greater freedom in their choice of doctors. A working group comprising representatives of associations for the disabled, doctors, and the sickness funds was to be set up to identify which conversions are possible and which can be sponsored by social insurance funds. Migrants are another group of people experiencing barriers in the health system. Ethnic and cultural background, as well as language can all act as barriers to accessing and utilising health services. On the part of the health system there are large deficits in comprehensive translation and interpreting services, as well as, availability of patient information in the relevant native language. The municipality department for issues related to integration and diversity (Magistratsabteilung für Integrations- und Diversitätsangelegenheiten, MA17) was founded in 2004 to meet the increasing needs and demands of ethnic diversity and integration in Vienna. One of the four areas of responsibility is the field of community, social aspects and health. Studies in Vienna194 have shown that women with a migrant background call upon curative services more often than preventive services.195 E.g. according to the 1998 survey only a third of women originally born in Turkey, or former Yugoslavia, underwent a cervical smear or breast examination, compared with 90% and 78% of Austrian women respectively. According to the micro-census of 1999 in Vienna, female Turkish citizens more often seek out the services of paediatricians, but less frequently the services of gynaecologists, dentist and out-patient departments/clinics than women from former Yugoslavia or Austria. Special barriers also exist for older migrants, for instance, an individual is only eligible for a pension after 15 years of making contributions within the last thirty years. For many migrants this can only be achieved if insurance periods in their land of origin are credited, however, this is only possible if an agreement exists between the two countries, which is often not the case. Eligibility to claim federal nursing care allowance is linked with the drawing of a pension. Eligibility for nursing care allowance in Vienna is not linked with the drawing of a pension, but is linked with nationality. Those claiming nursing allowance must have Austrian citizenship or equivalent. In culinary and cultural terms nursing homes are more aligned to their Austrian residents. Migrants without Austrian nationality may not be able to cover the costs of a nursing home, and 194 Ludwig Bolzmann Institut für Frauengesundheitsforschung 1998, Wimmer-Puchinger B, Baldaszti E, et al. (2006). Austrian Women’s Health Report 2005/2006. Federal Ministry of Health and Women (BMGF) Eds.. Vienna (see also www.bmgf.gv.at) 195 Viennese Women’s Health Report (Wiener Frauengesundheitsbericht) 2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 76 are not eligible for public funds (social welfare), which demands Austrian nationality as a pre-requisite for support196. Pochobradsky E, Habl C, Schleicher B, et al. Soziale Ungleichheit und Gesundheit. Österreichisches Bundesinstitut für Gesundheitswesen (ÖBIG) Oktober 2002197, gives an overview of barriers to access determined from available literature, including no health insurance, fear of bureaucracy etc. Explanations for barriers Looking into the effect that unemployment has on the health of women has yielded differing results. Due to the remaining commitments that are often still carried out by women, such as, housework, children, caring for relatives, it is argued that the negative effects of unemployment are not as severe in women as men. However, studies have shown that women’s reactions to unemployment assimilate those of men in cases where the job becomes an integral part of the woman’s life. According to the Micro-census of 1999, unemployed women reported doing less to maintain their health than working women. They placed less importance on healthy nutrition, health promoting exercise, and undertook less physical activity in their free time. For men the differences between unemployed and employed persons were not as great.198 Ageing was also found to be a factor amongst women. It was found that visits to the gynaecologist decreased with increase in age (based on data from Mikrozensus 1999) – see Appendix 5. In a study carried out by ÖBIG two thirds of private carers receiving nursing care allowance described themselves as “almost always” or “now and then” overburdened. The responsibility, the excessive demands, and hopelessness of the situation are psychological burdens and could lead to negligence of the carers own health. In 2001 20.5% of families in Vienna there were single parent families, of these 83.9% are women. Although more single mothers with children younger than 15 years are working compared to married women with children or women with partners, an above average amount (31%) are at risk of poverty. Studies have shown that subjective health of single mothers is poorer than that of married women. Self-evaluation of health is strongly linked with level of satisfaction with income. Within the framework of a study of single mothers in Vienna, commissioned by the Viennese Chamber of Labour (Arbeiterkammer Wien) and carried out by the Institute of Conflict Research (Institut für Konfliktforschung) in 2001, it was found that the combination of financial and time burdens frequently leads to social and psychological isolation. Single mothers more frequently suffering with health problems or impairments are those with financial problems, poor social contacts or very young children in particular those with children under three years of age. Further it was investigated whether those people exempt from prescription charges make more use of the precautionary health examination than those who are not exempt of prescription charges. Here it was shown that socially weaker women (43% more), exempt from prescription charges go for a precautionary health examination. For men the opposite was the case fewer prescription charge exempt men went to the precautionary health examination.199 Austrian Social insurance is currently developing a call-recall system for their health examination programme (Vorsorgeuntersuchung). This should target insured based on demographic and socioeconomic criteria. Gender has been found to play a role in the use of preventive health care and practice of health promoting activities. The first Austrian Men’s Health Report 2004 looked into the preventive health care available and 196 www.wien.gv.at/ma47/koste.htm#betrag Pochobradsky, E., Habl, C., Schleicher, B., Hlava, A. (2002). Social inequality and health care. Study commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. Vienna. 198 Viennese Women’s Health Report (Wiener Frauengesundheitsbericht) 2006 199 Pochobradsky, E., Habl, C., Schleicher, B., Hlava, A. (2002). Social inequality and health care. Study commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. Vienna. 197 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 77 use of preventive health care by men. The background and motives behind men’s health behaviour were analysed by means of a telephone survey. Men were asked about interest in preventive services, main sources of information, to evaluate their own health, etc. unhealthy lifestyles linked with level of education, some factors with age, and some, e.g. poor nutrition also linked with living alone. In general men place most importance on a personal invitation to the precautionary health care examination. Studies have shown200, that although men are aware of the importance of preventive or precautionary health care they tend to wait until symptoms have persisted for a longer period of time or they feel unwell before visiting the doctor201. On a regional level the Viennese Men’s Health Report 1999 (Wiener Männergesundheitbericht 1999)202 found that 9% of Austrian men went to a precautionary health examination. In comparison 6.5% (below the national average) of Viennese men and 13% (above the national average) of those living in the Burgenland went to a precautionary health examination. The Vienna Health and Social Survey 2001 - Wiener Gesundheits- und Sozialsurvey 2001 also researched health behaviour with respect to gender and also age, as well as professional status. Lifestyle factors including nutrition, exercise, etc. were examined and to what extent people inform themselves of about what they can do for their health. Attitude and approach to personal health was found to be dependent on sex (with women tending to undertake more than men), health promoting activities increase with increasing age, and are also linked with educational level. Sources of information with regards age and sex were also looked at. Furthermore precautionary health care, in terms of additional insurance and with respect to age and sex, household income, professional status and sex, as well as use of precautionary health examination was investigated.203 For further investigation into utilization barriers see:204 • • • Women and health care institutions (2002)205 – ÖBIG Health and the risk of illness (2003)206 – ÖBIG Sozial benachteiligte Gruppen und Gesundheit – ÖBIG 3.7.5 Inequalities in utilization of health services in Austria207 To some extent this question has been addressed by the points made in the section “barriers in accessing preventive services”, with regards to how socio-economic, educational etc. factors impact on utilization of health services. The various country-wide health reports (Austrian Women’s Health Care Report 2005/2006, Austrian Diabetes Report 2004, Austrian Men’s Health Care Report 2004, Allergy Report 2006, Adipositas Report 2006), and the Viennese reports (Vienna Health- and Social Survey 2001, Vienna Men’s Health Care Report 1999, Vienna Women’s Health Care Report - unpublished) contain a large amount of data regarding the utilization of health services linked to age, sex, educational level, professional status. The relationship between the utilization of health care services, need and income has so far not been analysed in detail. Researchers of the Federal institute for health care (ÖBIG) undertook a comprehensive 200 Eurostat 2002, Alber/Kohler 2003 Habl C, Birner A, Hlava A, Winkler P, et al. (2004) 1. Austrian Report on Men’s Health taking spezial consideration of Men’s health prevention. Federal Ministry of Social Security, Generations and Consumer Protection (BMSG) Eds. Vienna. (see also www.bmgf.gv.at) 202 Schmeiser-Rieder A, Kunze M, et al. (1999). Viennese Men’s HealthReport 1999. Magistratsabteilung für Angelegenheiten der Landessanitätsdirektion, Dezernat II, Gesundheitsplanung Eds. Vienna. Juli 1999. 203 Friedl W, Stronegger W-J, Neuhold C et al. (2001). Vienna Health and Social Survey. Magistrate of the city of Vienna, Health Care Planning and Financial Management, Health care reporting. Eds., p.1 204 www.oebig.at 205 ÖBIG Eds.(2002). Women and health care insitutions. Commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women (BMFG). Vienna. (see also: www.oebig.at) 206 ÖBIG Eds. (2003). Health and risk of illness. Commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. Vienna. (see also www.oebig.at) 207 Univ.-Prof. Dr. Anita Rieder, Kitty Lawrence BEng., Mag. Joy Ladurner MSc. 201 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 78 analysis of the topic and provide the results of their research in the report “Social inequality and health care” which was published by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women in 2002. In principle people in Austria receive equal treatment, independent of their income. Social health insurance enables direct access to a comprehensive benefits package for nearly 98% of the population. Even though user charges do exist they hardly pose a significant barrier to access as they are accompanied by extensive exemption schemes. This is especially important for costly services such as hospital care or emergency services. Inequalities in the Austrian population related to health care are generally not originated in the health care system but are primarily based in other factors such as social factors (education, income, social status, environment and working conditions, long-term unemployment or significance of own health status). Inequalities are partially counteracted by the system of statutory health insurance which is based on the principle of solidarity and redistribution.208 Austria experiences an interrelationship between low income and poor subjective health status as well as varied utilization of health care services209 Individuals belonging to the “lower class” categorise their health status as poorer compared with individuals belonging to other classes. Persons of this group consult general practitioners more often but utilize less specialists and dentists. They are sick more frequently and consume more medication on a regular basis as somebody belonging to a higher social class. The ÖBIG examined whether there was a relationship between the lower number of specialist visits by poor people and their place of residence (urban or rural); this made little difference. Habl210 showed that socially disadvantaged individuals (in this study being the equivalent of persons exempt from the prescription charge) younger than 70 years visit physicians in private practices more often than persons obliged to pay the prescription charge. It is crucial to note that about 40% of the exemptions are based in the existence of a medical condition. For people older than 70 years the utilization behaviour of those exempt and those not exempt approximates again. This is most likely due to the fact that elderly people display similar disease patterns. Individuals exempt from the prescription charge are prescribed more medicines than individuals who are not exempt. This is independent of their sex and place of residence and applies to all age groups. Expenditures for drugs are also comparably higher. Access to ambulatory health services for individuals of a lower social class may be associated with longer commuting times and waiting times.211 When looking at preventive services it becomes obvious that people belonging to a lower social class attend health check ups less often and undertake fewer efforts to maintain their health status. Moreover they may have restricted access to information on health care.212 The regional sickness fund of Carinthia213 analysed its average yearly expenditure for patients according to their income. It found out that patients of the lowest income group are responsible for more than double the expenditures of patients of the highest income group. In general patients of lower income groups pay more user charges. For instance patients belonging to the income group €0-900 are responsible for causing yearly expenditures of €1,050 and pay €64 for user charges. The average yearly expenditure for patients belonging to the income group of €901-1,200 amounts to €961. Individuals of this group pay €89 user charges, representing about 7% of their income. 208 Pochobradsky, E., Habl, C., Schleicher, B., Hlava, A. (2002). Social inequality and health care. Study commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. Vienna. 209 Freidl et al. (2001). ″Associations of income with self-reported ill-health and health resources in a rural community sample of Austria.″ Sozial- und Präventivmedizin 46, pp.106-114 210 Habl, C. (2004). ″Options for reducing social inequalites in health care.″ WISO 2, pp. 93-104 211 Pochobradsky, E., Habl, C., Schleicher, B., Hlava, A. (2002). Social inequality and health care. Study commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. Vienna. 212 Habl, C. (2004). ″Options for reducing social inequalities in health care.″ WISO 2, pp. 93-104 213 Wurzer, A., Robinig, R., Rodler, J. (2004). User charges, a review for orientation. Klagenfurt, Regional sickness fund of Carinthia. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 79 In comparison patients pertaining to the income group of €3,000 and above produce yearly expenditures of €499 paying €54 user charges. On average patients of the regional sickness fund of Carinthia cause yearly expenditures of €852 and pay €68 user charges. The data showed that patients exempt from the prescription charge on average caused a more than double amount of expenses than patients not exempt. This may partially be related to the fact that patients are exempt due to a medical condition. In the income group €0-900 patients exempt from the prescription charge cause expenditures of €2,136 in comparison to €808 of those not exempt and in the same income interval (both averages). 81% of the patients exempt from the prescription charge are pensioners. When analysing the group of patients which is responsible for using 50% of all sickness fund expenditure (7% of the patients, 6% of the insured), the high users, it was proven that these more frequently come from lower income classes (€0-900, 8% of men, 7% of women) than from higher income groups (€2,701-3,000: 2% of men i.e. women). Two thirds of the heavy users in the income group €0-900 are women. Judging by these results it may be deducted that sickness more often occurs in combination with age and low income. Summing up, it is recorded that income does play a significant role for the individual health status (morbidity, mortality) thus also influencing utilization of health care services. However other aspects such as personal risk factors (disability, sex, lifestyle), factors related to health care provision as well as workrelated factors, living conditions and other circumstances are of great significance.214 Statistics show that average expenses for health care increase with age and decrease with higher income. In Austria there is little indication that health services are rather used by individuals with higher income than by individuals with lower income meaning that consumption tends to be based in need (e.g. individuals with a higher income visit specialists on average more often than individuals with a low income). It seems however that no significant financial barriers exist in the Austrian health care system because individuals with low incomes tend to utilize more services than persons with a higher income. However is should be noted that socially disadvantaged people reported greater difficulties in terms of reachability of health services (commuting time) and had to accept longer waiting times in ambulatory institutions.215 This fact will most likely be more relevant in the context of elective care, but hardly apply to emergency care. With respect to this topic one can also refer to the reduction in waiting times for individuals with private health insurance. Differences across education groups Based on results of the Micro census undertaken in 1999, participation in health check-ups increases with higher education. Graduates of schools providing higher technical and vocational education (berufsbildende höhere Schulen) are the most frequent consumers of health check-ups (22.3%), individuals who attended Academic secondary schools (Allgemein höher bildende Schulen) and university graduates216 show comparably lower levels of utilization than persons attending vocational schools for apprentices (Abgänger einer Pflichtschule mit Lehre), 18.3% and 18.1% respectively compared to 20%. The average number of visits of general practitioners falls with increasing level of education. Whilst graduates of vocational schools without apprenticeships visit a general practitioner on average 5.39 times a year, university graduates display a yearly average of 2.85 visits. The same applies to visits of ambulatory clinics i.e. out-patient departments. These are equally accessed more by persons with a lower education. 214 Pochobradsky, E., Habl, C., Schleicher, B., Hlava, A. (2002). Social inequality and health care. Study commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. Vienna. 215 Pochobradsky, E., Habl, C., Schleicher, B., Hlava, A. (2002). Social inequality and health care. Study commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. Vienna. 216 Including educational establishments, comparable to a university LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 80 Contrary results are reported for visits of dentists. The average number of yearly visits is higher for people with a higher level of education (no consistent increase). Graduates of schools providing higher technical and vocational training consult dentists most often, namely on average 1.57 times a year. Inequalities at ambulatory care level In the course of the Micro census 1999 the consumption of various health care services was assessed. Participation in health check-ups varies regionally, whereby the highest population shares attending it were found in Burgenland (25.1%) and in Styria (24.4%). Participation was lowest in Vienna (11.4%) and in Lower Austria (12.2%). Access generally increases with urbanity of the population; it is however significantly lower in Vienna. In 2005, for the first time a decrease in the access to health check-ups was experienced. Before that participation had constantly been increasing. In 2005 participation was highest in Vorarlberg (22.9%), followed by Tyrol (20.9%) and Carinthia (17.2%), it was lowest in Lower Austria (4.9%), Vienna (8.7%) and Upper Austria (9.2%).217 The number of average visits of general practitioners per year was highest in Lower Austria, Upper Austria and Styria, lowest in Vorarlberg and Salzburg. Gynaecologists were consulted most often in Carinthia, doctors for Internal Medicine by men in Styria and Carinthia and by women in Tyrol, Styria and Lower Austria. Paediatricians in Vienna experienced most visits, other medical specialists in Carinthia and Lower Austria (men) and in Lower Austria and Vienna for women respectively. Ambulatory clinics were consulted most often per year in Vienna and in Styria and least often in Carinthia and Vorarlberg. Citizens in Lower Austria, Carinthia and Vienna consult dentists frequently, individuals in Burgenland and Upper Austria visit dentists least. Inequalities at hospital level In 2005 an average of 273.21 inpatient stays were registered per 1,000 inhabitants in Austria (excluding 0day stays). Regional disparities were between 202.86 stays in Burgenland and 316.26 in Salzburg. Average inpatient stays in hospitals funded by the federal health funds in 2005 amounted to 243.66 stays, the least were registered in Burgenland (188.26), the most in Upper Austria (279.71). Average length of stay in Austrian hospitals was situated at 6.58 days in 2005218. Tirol experienced the lowest length of stay at 5.17 days, Lower Austria the highest, at 9.64 days. Average length of stay in hospitals funded by the federal health funds in 2005 amounted to 5.93 days, whereby patients in Burgenland spent least time in hospital (4.82 days) and patients in Styria most (6.59 days). Since 1995 the length of stay has dropped considerably in all federal states.219 The average length of stay for all Austrian hospitals, adjusted for (excluding) the long-term stays (> 28 days) and the 0-day stays, was situated at 6.35 days in 2005 and at 5.80 days in hospitals funded by the federal health funds. Length of stay was lowest in Vorarlberg (5.26 days in all hospitals, 5.24 in fund hospitals respectively), it was highest in Styria (7.04) and in Vienna respectively (6.33 days).220 217 ORF, accessed at http://oesterreich.orf.at/stories/136476/ on 14/09/2006 All inpatient days, all admissions (Austria total) 219 Yearly average population: Statistics Austria http://www.statistik.at/fachbereich_03/bevoelkerung_tab1.shtml, Hospital admissions, length of stay: BMGF, received 21/09/2006, own calculations 220 Jahresdurchschnittsbevölkerung: Statistik Austria http://www.statistik.at/fachbereich_03/bevoelkerung_tab1.shtml, Stationäre Aufenthalte, durchschnittliche Aufenthaltsdauer: BMGF, erhalten 21/09/2006, eigene Berechnungen 218 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 81 Inequalities across social health insurance funds Not only the prescriptions per insured but also the costs per insured (for medicines) were lowest for the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA) in 2005, being 11.7 prescriptions and €284.23 per insured and highest for the occupational sickness funds, amounting to 27.1 prescriptions and €502.05 per insured for medicines221. On average the number of prescriptions per insured of all sickness funds was situated at 17.0 and the costs per insured (for medicines) at €337.92. Costs per prescription varied between €17.48 (sickness fund of the farmers) and €24.20 (Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business). Medical devises were, in 2004, prescribed most at the regional sickness funds (0.93 prescriptions per insured), least often at the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (0.30). Costs per insured (for medical devices) varied between €39.03 (SVA) and €91.62 (occupational sickness funds). The costs per prescription were situated in the range of €56.44 (regional sickness funds) and €121.98 (occupational funds). The following funds were above the average of €63.86: Occupational sickness funds, Insurance fund of the Austrian Mining and Industry, insurance fund of the Austrian Civil Servants, Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA) and the Austrian Social Insurance Fund of the Farmers. Days spent in hospital per case in 2005 were between 6.8 days and 7.9 days. Insured with the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA) experienced the lowest average number of days, insured of the occupational funds and the social insurance fund of the Farmers the highest number of days. On average insured spent 7.1 days per case in hospital.222 Billed cases per contract physician in Austria (all billing entities, Verrechnungsstellen) amounted to 4,467 cases for all § 2 funds (all medical specialties) in 2005. Fewest cases per physician were billed in Vorarlberg (4,141), most in Upper Austria (4,664). The fee per case (billed fee per case, for all medical specialties) ranged between €42.38 in Upper Austria and € 51.70 in Lower Austria. The fee per case in Lower Austria, Vorarlberg, Salzburg, Carinthia, Burgenland and Tyrol was found to be above the average fee of all § 2 billing entities. The fee per billed physician (in €1,000) was situated between €193.54 in Carinthia and €219.14 in Lower Austria. The billing entities of Lower Austria, Salzburg, Tyrol, Styria and Vorarlberg were above the average of all § 2 billing entities which amounted to €205.62 (all medical specialties). 223 3.7.6 Measures to improve access to care in Austria Insurance coverage Access to health services is guaranteed for most Austrians by means of coverage by social health insurance. In Austria social insurance is governed by law224 and is based on the principle of compulsory insurance. It encompasses the branches of health insurance, accident insurance and pension insurance (social insurance in a narrow sense) as well as, unemployment insurance225 (social insurance in the broad sense). In 2005 97.8 percent226 of the population (about 8.2 million) were covered by social health insurance. Inclusion in the 221 Since 1.1.2005 merged with the insurance fund of the Austrian Railway Industry. The new body is the Insurance fund for the Austrian Railway and Mining industries 222 Hauptverband der österreichsichen Sozialersicherung (2005). Statistical handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2005. Vienna 223 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger. HVB, “Red Book” Database, based on the costing statistics for physicians. accessed 05/01/2006 224 General Social Insurance Law (ASVG), Special Laws GSVG (for the self-employed), B-KUVG (for civil servants), BSVG (for farmers), FSVG (for independent free-lance, self-employed) as well as respective amendments 225 The insurance of the unemployed is organised by the Public employment service (Arbeitsmarktservice) and is independent 226 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, including individuals insured at health care institutions (Krankenfürsörgeeinrichtungen) LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 82 community of insured persons follows after starting a job or by fulfilling other compulsory insurance criteria (compulsory insurance) or by way of a derivative insurance cover (e.g. joint-insured dependants). For those without compulsory insurance there is the possibility of voluntary insurance. Pensioners, Unemployed, Asylum seekers under federal supervision are also covered by social health insurance. In Austria, at the end of June 2003 up to 3.1% of the resident population from age 15 years are not covered by national health insurance.227 Of these 0.7% had a substitutive private insurance (opting-out cases) and 2.4% were without any (registered) entitlement to services in case of illness.228 Health insurance benefits The service coverage of the legal health insurance is comprehensively regulated in the social insurance laws (ASVG, B-KUVG, GSVG and BSVG).229 Health insurance funds retain only limited scope. Services can be classified in respect of their legal nature (compulsory services, voluntary services or compulsory duties) or by the way in which they are provided (allowance in kind or cash benefits).230 The insured person (on submission of an insurance case as well as fulfilment of certain criteria231) has an enforceable right to compulsory insurance (e.g. treatment of illness). With the compulsory services, differentiation must be made between the minimum legal service requirements (type, scope, and conditions are governed by law) and the statutory additional services (health insurance funds are permitted to define more comprehensive services in their statutes (according to grounds, level, or duration), as long as these remain within the scope of the model statutes set out by the Hauptverband). The insured person has no enforceable legal claim to voluntary services (e.g. measures to consolidate health), these are granted at the dutiful discretion of the health insurance fund. The insured person has no individual legal claim to compulsory duties (e.g. medical rehabilitation), these are to be provided at the dutiful discretion of the insurance fund. Differences in the spectrum of services provided by different insurance funds can occur due to various reasons: - Based on variations in legal regulations (when utilising inpatient care, services according to the legal health insurance are available for all B-KUVG (civil servants) insured and for some GSVG insured232 (self-employed) in the private ward (Sonderklasse).233 - Based on variations in contractual rules234. (Insurance funds have varying contractual arrangements with providers of health care services. These variations can not be entirely explained by the individual sickness fund but are also dependent on the contract partner i.e. the representative association). - Services provided (the benefits package) are influenced by the financial situation of the sickness fund, for instance the regional fund in Vienna does not reimburse Spa treatment. - Services can, depending on the sickness fund, require the patient to cover different levels of copayments. 227 Fuchs, M, et al. (2003). Quantitative and qualitative assessment and analysis of individuals not covered by health insurance in Austria, Final report October 2003, Report commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. 228 Maximum values 229 Moreover in the statutes of the Social insurance funds and in the Sickness rules (Krankenordnung) 230 § 121 ASVG 231 Seidl, W. (2002), Social Insurance Law. Skriptum, Graz, Neuer Wissenschaftlicher Verlag. Reiter, G. (2002). ″Compulsory insurance versus the obligation to take out insurance – more than a play of words?.″ WISO 3, pp. 7990. 232 Those consuming benefits in cash. Actual benefits are defined by law or the statutes of the insurance fund. Regulations apply nationwide as both insurance funds are nationwide funds. 234 Schrammel, W. (2002). Report of the chair of the expert commission „Compulsory insurance – the obligation to take out insurance“, accessible at http://www.auva.at/mediaDB/63990.PDF#search=%22Schramml%20Expertenkommission%20Pflichtversicherun g%22. 233 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 83 - The scope of benefits provided may vary between branches of sickness funds, e.g. in health insurance (sufficient, appropriate, not exceeding the necessary amount) and in accident insurance (with all appropriate means) and also depend on the insured event (illness vs. occupational illness). Principle of benefits in kind Services are provided either as allowance in kind (in form of tangible assets or provision of service) or as cash benefits. The first can be called upon by contractual partners (contractual facilities, contract doctors) or the insurance funds own facilities. The latter may be claimed once or repeatedly (ongoing). Health insurance primarily provides benefits in kind235, cash benefits predominate in accident and pension insurance.236 There are variations in the terms for persons entitled to cash benefit insured by the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA). Using services as benefits in kind facilitates access to health care services for insured, regardless of their socio-economic status. Utilising health care services belonging to the benefits package of social health insurance does, with the exception of partial user charges, not result in any direct costs for the insured population. When a contract doctor is consulted there is a regulation prohibiting him to accept extra payments. The contract doctor is not allowed to, in the same consultation, bill services of social health insurance partially on the sickness fund and partially privately. Some benefits of social health insurance are granted as cash benefits and are calculated based on the income of the insured. These include sickness allowance, which is supposed to substitute income in the event of illness, daily allowance (Taggeld) based on the GSVG, maternity allowance (Wochengeld), business assistance/maternity allowance for self-employed/farmers (GSVG/BSVG) or allowances for travel expenses or funeral expenses. Cash benefits which do not depend on the insured’s income are for instance child care benefits237, allowances for child care benefits (Zuschuss zum Kinderbetreuungsgeld) or allowances in the context of rehabilitation treatment e.g. for the adaption of an apartment or car. Cash benefits are primarily provided in the insurance branches of accident- and pension insurance. Exemptions from cost-sharing When using health services through social health insurance insured are, on some occasions, confronted with user charges. The Austrian system has a variety of exemptions, which can, when patients are in need of care, enable i.e. facilitate access to care. Exemptions are described subsequently. Regulations on exemptions are stated either in the social insurance laws or in the directives issued by the sickness funds or the Hauptverband. Exemptions may originate in the special need of social protection (income) of the insured, in cases of hardship (contagious or chronic illness, individuals requiring dialysis treatment) or in the existence of a certain insured event (maternity), the preventive character of the benefit or the age of the insured. For a range of services, as already mentioned above, exemptions are granted to insured who exhibit a special need of social protection corresponding to the directives of the Hauptverband (e.g. for physician services, pharmaceuticals, therapeutic aids, hospital care). 235 Federal Ministry of Social Insurance, Generations and Consumer Protection, BMSGK (2003). Social protection in Austria, an overview, Vienna. Kind, M. (2005). My rights as a patient. Vienna, Verlag des Österreichischen Gewerkschaftsbundes GmbH. 236 Seidl, W. (2002), Social Insurance Law. Skriptum, Graz, Neuer Wissenschaftlicher Verlag. Reiter, G. (2002). ″Compulsory insurance versus the obligation to take out insurance – more than a play of words?.″ WISO 3, pp. 79-90. 237 There is a limit on extra earnings of € 14,600 € per year LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 84 Furthermore there are a number of exemptions for self-employed (GSVG insured) for services provided by physicians and other health care professionals such as psychotherapists, psychologists, ergo therapists, etc. which are stated in § 86 para.5 GSVG, amongst others for the treatment of children, notifiable diseases, dialysis treatment following kidney disease or the donation of organs. For BSVG insured exemptions for services provided by physicians and other health professionals can be found in § 80 para.3 BSVG. Therapeutic aids and devices are provided without any user charges for ASVG, B-KUCG, GSVG and BSVG insured as long as the insured is younger than 15 years of age or is entitled to increased family allowances. For ASVG insured the same criteria apply for visual aids. GSVG insured, who are only insured as recipients of an orphan pension do not pay any co-payments for social health insurance benefits such as dental care, orthopaedic treatment, skeletonised metal dentures (skeletierte Metallgerüstprothesen), metal crowns or anchor teeth (Klammerzähne) for partial dentures. No user charges have to be paid for hospital care related to the insured event of maternity or to organ donation. For co-payments based on both the Hospital Act and the Social insurance Act there usually is a maximum number of days for which they have to be paid, e.g. 28 days for user charges according to the Hospital Act. The following paragraph briefly describes exemptions from prescription charges and exemption criteria for the utilization of therapeutic aids and devices. Exemptions of the prescription charge (ASVG, GSVG, B-KUVG, BSVG) a) By act of law – individuals with notifiable, contagious diseases b) By directive of the Hauptverband – individuals exhibiting a special need of social protection • Recipients of income support (net income for single persons < €690.00, for married couples or cohabitees < €1,055.99) • Recipients of income support related to a pension of pension insurance • Recipients of supplementary support (Ergänzungszulage) • Individuals providing evidence on above-average expenses due to suffering or ailment and whose monthly net income do not surpass a certain amount of money (singles: €793.50, married couples or cohabitees €1.214.39) For each child entitled to maintenance the above mentioned fees are increased by €72.32. B-KUVG: Once the prescription charge has been paid a refund is possible BSVG: Particularities for recipients of income benefits according to § 140 para.7 BSVG These exemptions also apply to the e-card service charge. Exemptions from co-payments for therapeutic aids and devices (Heilbehelfe, Hilfsmittel) (ASVG, GSVG, B-KUVG, BSVG) a) By law for insured or dependants younger than 15 years b) By law for insured or dependants who are entitled to increased family benefits (irrespective of age) c) When providing evidence for special need of social protection according to the directive issued by the Hauptverband (see prescription charge exemptions) d) In the context of services provided for medical rehabilitation Particularities for B-KUVG and BSVG insured: see exemptions of the prescription charge Further financial assistance for insured Social insurance funds can grant insured who are in situations requiring special consideration financial allowances of the assistance fund (Unterstützungsfonds) (see § 84 ASVG). This is usually exercised in LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 85 cases of emergency, e.g. if an insured is confronted with extraordinarily high expenses in the course of using physician services and is in financial distress. Financial allowances originating from the assistance fund represent a voluntary benefit of social insurance for which insured do not have a legal title. The funds are to be provided in proportion with the respective directives, taking the family-, income and assetsituation of the supported individual into consideration.238 Social insurance contributions Social insurance contributions are defined by Federation and agreed on by parliament. The level of the contributions is calculated by the contribution base and the contribution rates applicable, which depend on the type of employment in the different federal laws. Contribution rates for social health insurance are independent of the personal risk of the insured and situated between 7.1% and 9.1%.239 Deviations result from historical developments, slightly different benefit packages and distinctions in the characteristics of the insured groups. About 77% of all insured in Austria are insured under the General social insurance law (ASVG), 8.5% under the Social insurance law for civil servants (B-KUVG), 6.8% under the social insurance law for self-employed (GSVG) and 4.6% under the social insurance law for farmers240. For the employed insured roughly half of the social insurance contributions are paid by the employer, the other half is paid by themselves. Only in accident insurance the employer covers the whole fee. For insured under the ASVG and the B-KUVG the earnings limit for chargeable contributions in health-, accident- and pension insurance amounts to €3,750 monthly, for insured under the BSVG to €4,375 monthly and for insured under the GSVG in health- and pension insurance to €4.575 monthly, the contribution for accident insurance is a monthly lump sum payment. Location Plan (Stellenplan) The Location Plan forms part of the general contract negotiated between the Hauptverband, the regional sickness fund and the Medical Chamber of the respective federal state and defines the number and the geographical distribution of contract doctors. By means of the Location Plan insured should be granted a fair (corresponding to demand) and efficient provision of care through physicians in primary care. If required, new contract posts are established, sometimes contract posts are also closed down or relocated (depending on demand and population development). An increase in the number of contract doctors may though not always be necessary. Frequently patients are only lacking information about the location of the contract doctor closest to them which they receive from their sickness fund. Based on § 135 para.2 ASVG the insured should be able to choose from at least two physicians or group practices appropriate for the kind of care required who can be reached within a moderate time. Practically great variations in the density of health care providers exist when comparing urban and rural areas, especially the density of specialists is a lot lower in the latter areas. Financial incentives for doctors to run a practice in structurally disadvantaged areas are not provided by the sickness funds or the Medical Chamber but partially by the municipalities. Health insurance funds react to this problem by sometimes allowing the sharing of a contract physician’s post. In order to assess the equitable provision of services in a region not only the number of health care providers should be analysed but also their availability i.e. their opening hours and actual working hours. 238 Web portal of Austrian Social Insurance, accessed at www.sozialversicherung.at, on 17/06/2006 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB (2006). Social security data (contributions) in the Austrian Social Insurance 2006. cut-off-date 1 January 2006, Version 13.02.2006 240 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 239 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 86 Reimbursement of travel expenses241 In 2005 social health insurance spent a total of €168 million on travel- and transportation expenses (around 1.41% of total expenditure).242 The reimbursement of travel- i.e. transportation costs which the patient incurs in the course of accessing physician services because of the distance between the medical practice and his apartment, is a voluntary benefit of social health insurance and can be granted in proportion to the regulations of the statutes of the individual sickness fund (see § 135 para.4 ASVG). The extent of the reimbursement depends on the local circumstances as well the cost resulting from the cheapest type of public transport (private car). If necessary the statutes of the sickness fund can also include regulations to cover travel expenses for a second person accompanying the patient (for instance in the case of children or fragile individuals). Partially the reimbursement is dependent on a defined minimum distance or is only free of charge for a certain group of patients (individuals exempt from prescription charge, certain types of medical treatment). The regional sickness fund of Vienna stopped covering travel expenses in December 2004. In case the patient cannot be expected to use public transport due to physical or mental reasons (e.g. the patient cannot walk) the sickness fund is obliged to cover transportation costs to access services according to the prearranged contractual fees. This benefit is a compulsory duty of the sickness funds which is to be provided in accordance with the dutiful discretion of the insurance fund Transportation expenses (for national transportation) may be granted in the course of inpatient treatment, for transportation in the nearest appropriate hospital or from the hospital to the apartment of the patient, for medically induced transferral from one hospital to the nearest adequate hospital, for ambulatory treatment with the nearest contract physician or contract group practice or in the nearest contract institution i.e. back to the apartment of the patient or for the formfitting adjustment of medical aids or devices. The prerequisites for the use of transportation services by means of patient transport ambulance are stated in the statutes of the insurance fund. Apart from a few exceptions (e.g. emergency) the transportation requires proof of medical necessity by certification of a physician (see § 135 para.5 ASVG). In their statutes the sickness funds regulate that the insured has to meet certain co-payments for travel expenses i.e. transportation costs or define exemption criteria (e.g. for dialysis treatment). The expenses for air emergency are only reimbursed by the health insurance fund if the patient cannot be expected to be transported by land either because of his condition or urgency of the case. Travel expenses in the course of treatment abroad are not covered by all health insurance funds. They are only reimbursed if it was not possible to perform the necessary treatment within the country and/or they were preauthorised by the sickness fund. Most health insurance funds recommend signing up for private travel and repatriation insurance before going abroad.243 In the context of accidents related to sports and tourism recovery costs for transportation to the valley are not reimbursed. Transportation costs are only covered if the transportation by air would have also been necessary in the valley. Accidents taking place during school ski courses, excursions and similar events are generally categorised as accidents at work. 241 § 135 ASVG (General Social Security Act), Webpages of social insurance funds, accessible via the Web portal of Austrian social insurance at www. sozialversicherung.at, accessed 19/05/2006 242 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2006), Handbook of Austrian social insurance 2006, Vienna. 243 For coverage of costs for benefits not reimbursed by social health insurance LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 87 Average distance to health care institutions The Austrian Federal Institute for health care (Österreichisches Bundesinstitut im Gesundheitswesen, ÖBIG) administers a database, the “Austrian Health Care Information System “(ÖGIS), which contains a wide range of health care relevant information. A reduced version, REGIS, is publicly accessible on the internet and provides users with predefined analysis on the topics: demography, life expectancy, mortality, hospital admissions, lifestyle and traffic accidents. ÖGIS incorporates a reachability model with which the user can, provided he knows the institution he is looking for i.e the institution is defined in the system, calculate the distance between a certain point and the institution. Calculations are performed based on individual road traffic, not on public transport.244 Inquiries can be handled on request by experts at the ÖBIG and have to be paid for. A number of federal states contact the ÖBIG on a regular basis. According to Dr. Fülöp from the ÖBIG other institutions in Austria involved in comparable areas of research are the Institute for land use planning and rural development at the University of Natural Resources and Applied Life Sciences (Universität für Bodenkultur) in Vienna as well as the Institute for urban- and rural research at the Vienna Technical University. Regulations in the general contract of social insurance The general contract between the Hauptverband and the federal Medical Chamber includes various regulations to ensure equal access to providers of medical services. Conditions may vary according to service provider. Physicians or other health professionals who have signed a contract with social health insurance are obliged to treat insured patients and their dependants, providing a defined range of benefits, for account of social health insurance (obligation to treat).245 Furthermore, public hospitals are, according to the Hospital Act, committed to admit patients with social health insurance coverage requiring inpatient care to the general ward. Moreover Patients whose “physical or mental condition requires immediate inpatient care because of danger of life or because of the danger of an otherwise not preventable severe danger to their health” must not be rejected. Mentally ill may be obliged to accept an admission to hospital.246 Public hospitals are only permitted to deny admission of patients in case no beds are free or if they do not provide enough i.e. the appropriate medical equipment necessary for treatment (exception emergency).247 Ambulatory contract doctors are however, according to the regulations of the general contact, allowed to, in justified cases, reject treatment of an insured person. Doctors have (apart from in the event of an emergency or severe symptoms) no obligation to treat private patients. Private patients may not be favoured to patients covered by social health insurance (prohibition to discriminate). The physician is only allowed to reject or interrupt treatment if he states cogent reasons (lack of trust, lack in qualification or training).248 In case he is not in command of the knowledge or skills necessary he ought to turn down treatment requests based on his own estimation. Doctors may also deny treatment to new patients as long as this is in the interest of their present patients and counteracts an overload of their practice.249 On demand doctors have to communicate and document the reason for the denial of the patient to the health insurance fund.250 244 Dr. Gerhard Fülöp (Österreichisches Bundesinstitut im Gesundheitswesen, ÖBIG). 16/06/2006. Tomandl, T. (2005). What you always wanted to know about Social Insurance. Vienna, Manz. 246 Kind, M. (2005). My rights as a patient. Vienna, Verlag des Österreichischen Gewerkschaftsbundes GmbH. 247 Web portal of Austrian Social Insurance, accessed at www.sozialversicherung.at, 248 Doctors’ Law (Ärztegesetz) 249 Brodil, W., Windisch-Graetz, M. (2005). Main features of Social Law. Vienna, WUV Universitätsverlag. General contract 250 Dr. Gregoritsch (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HBV). Interview 25 November 2005 245 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 88 In the event of an emergency (absolutely necessary first aid) all health care providers are strictly obliged to provide assistance. Statutory social health insurance reduces the possibility of risk selection in social insurance (by the insured or by the insurance fund) by far. Risk selection by contract providers is counteracted by measures such as regulations in the general contract (obligation to treat, prohibition to discriminate), by regulations related to reimbursement as well as incentives (e.g. encouraging coordinating activities). However cases are reported in which for instance private patients on waiting lists for elective surgical procedures are put at an advantage. Even if the contract doctor of social insurance is, by means of regulations in the general contract, prohibited to favour private patients over patients with social health insurance it may still be the case that he favours insured of the latter group who are not insured under the ASVG over those who are insured under the ASVG because the remaining health insurance funds usually reimburse their contract partners on a fee-for services basis. To verify this assumption further research ought to be carried out. Opening hours/ Waiting times Contract doctors have to work a minimum of 20 hours per week as contract doctors for social health insurance. They are obliged to comply with the minimum working hours defined in the general contract with social insurance. Notwithstanding this regulation, shortages in the provision of care occur for certain specialties at given times because opening hours are not coordinated regionally or within districts. In the general contract of the regional sickness fund of Upper Austria the regulation on opening hours is as follows: “the weekly opening hours should be no less than 20 hours. The practice of the physician has to be open during at least 5 working days (Monday to Saturday). Consultation hours are to be provided on at least two afternoons i.e. evenings of the week, beginning at 14:00 (lasting 3 hours) or at 15:00 (lasting two hours). Either of these consultation periods can be substituted by a two hour consultation period on Saturday.251” Contract doctors must inform their patients about any substitutions by other colleagues. In the evaluation form assessing quality in physician practices the ÖQMed (Austrian Association for Quality Assurance and Quality Management in Medicine Plc.) asks doctors if patients with acute symptoms are given an appointment at short notice or, if applicable, are referred to an outpatient’s department or physician’ emergency service.252 The motivation for physicians is to assess the quality of their practices by filling out a questionnaire (60 questions). The quality indicators in the questionnaire were defined by the physicians in co-operation with a scientific board of experts. For the time being it only includes criteria belonging to the dimensions of structure or process quality. The responses are checked if they are plausible. In addition random inspections of practices take place. By 2008 about 15,000 practices will be evaluated, which are then re-assessed every two to three years.253 Evaluations started mid April 2006.254 The responsibility for the quality assessment lies with the ÖQMed Association. 251 Regional sickness fund of Upper Austria (2006). General contract (with physicians). Dated 1 July 2006, Linz. Austrian Association for quality assurance and quality mangement in medicine Plc. (Österreichische Gesellschaft für Qualitätssicherung und Qualitätsmanagement in der Medizin GmbH ,ÖQMed), Evaluation questions for doctors, Version 1.0. Developed 14 March 2006, accessed at http://www.oeqmed.at/fileadmin/Downloads/LETZTVERSION_Evaluierungsfragen_Mar06.pdf on 17/0672006 253 HÖ (2005). ″ Quality in physician practices.″ Medical Tribune 18, accessed at http://www.medicaltribune.at/dynasite.cfm?dssid=4170&dsmid=63806&dspaid=484448 on November 18th 2005 254 Austrian Medical Chamber (2006). PK „Quality assurance in Austrian physician practices“, dated 15 March 2006, accessed at: http://www.aek.or.at/cache/000000000020060315112322.xml/PK-Unterlage%202006-03-15.pdf, on 11/04/2006 252 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 89 Initiatives to reduce cultural barriers Social insurance institutions increasingly provide information for non-German speaking insured and patients, for instance examination forms for preventive services (health-check-ups) as well as other forms are available in various languages (e.g. Turkish, Serbian, Croatian). Further activities for foreigners i.e. migrants i.e. persons whose native language is not German are translators’ services, multilingual signs or direction signs or health care centres for migrants. The ZEBRA255 association (Centre for medical, juridical and cultural assistance for foreigners (migrants and refugees) in Austria) in Graz offers health related services such as counselling and the procurement of medical treatment. At road shows on various health related topics in the city hall in Vienna (Gesundheitstage) the regional sickness funds of Vienna assigns an additional member of staff, speaking Turkish, to their information booth, thus trying to address the needs of their insured Turkish population. According to the ombudswoman of the regional sickness fund of Vienna the health insurance funds cooperate with associations offering assistance to foreigners and migrants, amongst others with the Austrian Integration Fund or with self help groups. In connection with migration and intercultural care in the inpatient sector the WHO conducted the project “Migrant friendly hospitals”.256 12 countries participated in the project coordinated by the Ludwig Boltzmann Institute for the Sociology and Health in Medicine in Vienna (LBI für Medizin und Gesundheitssoziologie). In the „Amsterdam declaration towards migrant friendly hospitals in an ethnoculturally diverse Europe“ 26 recommendations were elaborated such as developing co-operations with community organizations and advocacy groups who are knowledgeable about the issues of migrants and minority ethnic groups. This should encourage the development of a more culturally and linguistically appropriate delivery system.257 The reference hospital in Vienna was the Kaiser Franz Josef Spital.258 Other model projects in Austria on this topic are the participation in an EU project to promote equality of migrants259, a project for intercultural opening at the regional sickness fund of Styria, the opening of psychosocial counselling centres as well as a project at the hospital for nervous diseases Sigmund Freud.260 Moreover the project “Treatment of Turkish patients in hospitals in Vienna in their native language”261 In the Hanusch hospital of the regional sickness fund of Vienna the gynaecologist Dr. Eichbauer initiated a project for female Turkish patients. In the beginning Turkish and Austrian women patients were questioned on various topics. Based on their answers a list of problems was set up- At the same time hospital staff attended further education seminars in order to become more receptive to the issue. The result of the project is a catalogue of measures which can be applied universally, in any hospital. Furthermore Dr. Eichbauer and 255 Centre for sociomedical, legal and cultural support of foreigners/migrants, accessed at www.zebra.or.at Project Webpage of “Migrant friendly hospitals”: http://www.mfh-eu.net/public/home.htm 257 Amsterdam Declaration, accessed at: http://www.mfheu.net/public/files/european_recommendations/mfh_amsterdam_declaration_english.pdf, on September 9th 2006 258 Milijkovic, M. (2006). ″A wrong gesture and trust is lost, The Vienna Kaiser-Franz-Josef-Spital as example of a “migrantfriendly hospital.″ Der Standard, 12.06.06. 259 Webpage of the project „promoting equal chances of migrants” at https://www.wien.gv.at/euf/internet/AdvPrSrv.asp?Layout=psProjekt&Type=K&PROJEKTID=1936 260 Eichbauer, H. (2004). Lived integration in the hospital. Final report, Vienna 2004. Ludwig Boltzmann Institute for the Sociology of Health and Medicine (Eds.) (2003). Caring for migrant and minority patients in European hospitals. A review of effective interventions. Vienna, 2003 in Pammer, C., (2005). Migration und Public Health in Austria in Martin Sprenger Eds. (2005). Public Health in Österreich und Europa, Lengerich. Pabst Science Publishers. 261 Project description can be accessed at www.wien.gv.at 256 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 90 his co-workers offer to assist other institutions planning a similar project in reporting their experience or giving advice.262 The Public company for Health care and hospitals in Upper Austria, Gespag (OÖ Gesundheits- und Spitals AG, Gespag) offers its employees seminars on „transcultural care of patients with a different cultural background“ and „transcultural care in the area of obstetrics and gyneacology”. In one of their hospitals, the Wagner-Jauregg Hospital, a hospital for nervous diseases, the first intercultural outpatient department has been opened for foreign patients in need of psychiatric care.263 Initiatives aiming at informing and educating the insured population Health insurance funds inform their insured population by means of personal counselling, information brochures, their websites, journals or road shows. Needless to say that insured also receive information on health insurance benefits and possible user charges by their health care providers. Two health insurance funds have opened health information centres (Gesundheitsinformationszentren, GIZ), the regional sickness fund of Salzburg and the regional sickness fund of Burgenland. The GIZ in Salzburg264 is mainly orientated towards insured and offers information on topics such as health, illness and health promotion free of charge. Replying to a questionnaire the health insurance funds received in November 2005 the majority of them stated that they thought that their insured had a sufficient amount of information to facilitate choice. Information sources cited were the health insurance fund’s website, health information centres (described above) and magazines for insured or personal assistance provided by employees of the sickness fund. It should however be pointed out that whilst patients are provided with a range of information on health care providers as well as services granted by social health insurance, that there is no standardized information on the quality of services provided. In the future health insurance funds are planning to increase information supply for the following areas: preventive care (screening), case management i.e. disease management, Diabetes type II, preventive services. Proactive involvement of patients is intended in some areas, for instance preventive services will be supplemented by a call-recall system and individuals suffering from Diabetes type II will be given the option to take part in disease management programs. Other institutions informing patients about health care services reimbursed by social health insurance are for instance self help groups, patient initiatives or patient representatives. Barrier free access to health care services The year 2003 was the European year of people with disabilities. In this year Austrian social insurance set itself the target of improving access to medical institutions (barrier free, disabled accessible). Amongst other activities the barrier free status of physician practices was evaluated, in cooperation with other associations, in all federal states and an analysis for all sickness funds was performed.265 A symposium on the topic “physician without barriers” was organised by the Hauptverband, the working group for rehabilitation and the BIZEPS association on the 16th of October 2003. Other projects were mentioned within the scope of the symposium, such as a project organised by the healthy Vienna Fund “Women with disabilities at the gynaecologist”, moreover projects of the BIZEPS 262 Hanuschkrankenhaus (Hanusch Hospital), Dr. Eichbauer, interview 26 June 2006 (telephone) Rohrhofer, M. (2006). ″No coffee or biscuits during ramadan, transcultural care and psychiatry in a hospital for paediatrics and a hospital for nervous diseases in Linz, Der Standard. 12.06.06. 264 Somweber, M., (2002). Health Care Information Centre, GIZ–a pilot project of the regional sickness fund of Salzburg. In Meggeneder, O., Hengl, W. Eds. (2002). The informed patient – claim and reality. Linz, pp. 123-133 265 Stowasser, S. (2004). ″Barrier free access to physician practices– country-wide assessment of the current status.″ Soziale Sicherheit 5, pp. 192-193 263 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 91 association “disabled persons in hospitals and other health care institutions” or a project of the city Wels in Upper Austria “Wels paves the way”. Last year in June a reference book with the title “ill, disabled, unobstructed” was presented to the public in Vienna. The reference book is the result of the BIZEPS project “Disabled persons in health care institutions in Vienna” and includes 362 health care institutions and 79 pharmacies which were all accurately measured.266 Subsidies for barrier free building are granted by the Ministry of Social Security, Generations and Consumer Protection or by the federal social welfare office. In their general contracts some health insurance funds have already defined that from a certain point in time onwards newly created contract posts (places) have to exhibit barrier free access to their practice. Contracts already existing at that date are granted a transition period of usually 5 years. Sickness funds have partially defined a minimum share of practices which have to be barrier free by a defined date. Criteria for barrier free access are stated in the annex of the group practice framework arrangement with the Austrian Medical Chamber. The remaining sickness funds are planning to integrate such a regulation in their general contracts soon. The regional sickness fund of Vorarlberg and the regional Medical Chamber have come to an agreement whereby newly opened practices have to prove barrier free access. This is already stated in the advertisement for the post/job. The same applies to the regional sickness fund of Burgenland. A commitment of the future contract doctor, to make an effort to implement barrier free access, has been included in the application process for free contract posts, in the ranking criteria (Reihungskriterienverordnung). By means of written consent the physician agrees to, following the ÖNORM 1600 “barrier free building” and the ÖNORM 1601 “special building provisions for disabled and elderly persons” create barrier free access to his practice within an adequate period of time following the signing of the contract.267 The ASVG regulation on group practices included, for the first time, the legally binding prerequisite of proving barrier free access in order to sign a contract with social insurance. An insurance benefit which is supposed to improve i.e. facilitate access to care for disabled or patients with restricted mobility is the home visit. In the evaluation form on quality in physician practices the ÖQMed (Austrian Association for Quality Assurance and Quality Management in Medicine Ltd) asks physicians if patients have the option of enquiring about any existing barriers before coming to their practice. Beginning with June 2006 startup practices or succession practices are obliged to perform a consultation with a disability association according to § 6 Z1 QS-VO 2006. If the physician complies with the requirements for a barrier free practice he is from January 1, 2006 to be included in the list based on § 16 of this directive after the consultation. Furthermore the physician is questioned if, given the constructional circumstances, he makes an effort to facilitate access to his practice for patients with restricted mobility268. At www.praxisplan.at the Medical Chamber of Vienna offers patients looking for a contract doctor information on the doctor’s name, post code, sex, specialty, special training/diplomas, other activities, sickness funds, opening hours and language skills. In addition they provide information on the accessibility for disabled to the practice (disabled accessible yes/no (personal perception of doctor), performance data on 266 BIZEPS project “Disabled persons in health care institutions in Vienna”, accessed at http://www.service4u.at/blickkontakt/news.php?nr=6282 on 17/06/2006 267 Regional sickness fund of Vienna (2004), General contract (with physicians), 1 January 2004, Vienna. Medical Chamber of Lower Austria, application for a free place with social insurance (questionnaire), accessed at http://www.arztnoe.at/localfiles/5084_.pdf on 17/06/2006 268 Austrian Association for quality assurance and quality mangement in medicine Plc. (Österreichische Gesellschaft für Qualitätssicherung und Qualitätsmanagement in der Medizin GmbH ,ÖQMed), evaluation questions for doctors Version 1.0 developed on 14 March, accessed at http://www.oeqmed.at/fileadmin/Downloads/LETZTVERSION_Evaluierungsfragen_Mar06.pdf 17/06/2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 92 the accessibility of the practice). This information has been collected in cooperation with the association for disabled, BIZEPS, beginning in November 2005.269 In January 2006 the Federal equalization Act for disabled came into effect. The aim of this law is to “eliminate or reduce the discrimination against individuals suffering from disabilities thus ensuring equal participation of the disabled in community life and giving them the option of living a self-determined life” .270 Internet Applications The Web Accessibility Initiative (WAI) of the W3 consortium has in 1999 defined guidelines for Web Content Accessibility (WCAG) – guidelines for barrier free web content - which are valid in the whole world and are the basis for legalisation on barrier free design of information technology. The aim is to enable i.e. facilitate access to information for individuals with visual impairments as well as for blind or deaf people. WAI guidelines are recommended by the European Commission and have been implemented in many places in Austria. Three grades of conformity can be distinguished each defining a certain extent of barrier free access. The grades range from A to AAA whereby AAA is the highest. For example triple A ensures that text is supplied for each non-text element (picture, graph), that CSS (Cascading Style Sheets) and markups are used instead of pictures, colour contrasts as well as scalable formats of writing. In addition tables are to be avoided for layout, headings and listings should be provided with the respective explanations.271 In Austrian Social Insurance (web portal of the Austrian Social Insurance at www.sozialversicherung.at) the content (display of content only, not including services) meets conformity level A. The new applications meet WAI conformity level AAA. The reorganization to WAI AAA is planned for the second term in 2006 i.e. early in 2007.272 3.8 Patient pathways Countries differ in the typical patient pathway through the health system, with different initial points of contact, referral arrangements, waiting time guarantees, private alternatives, and cover of second opinions. In light of these differences, typical patient pathways from a selection of European countries are depicted individually in Appendix 6. 3.8.1 Patient pathway in Austria Before describing the pathway of a patient in the Austrian health care system it should be pointed out that the Austrian system grants not only contract partners but also patients a great deal of choice with respect to treatment. A comprehensive description of the huge variety of patient pathways cannot be performed in the course of this study. The reader should acknowledge that the following description only takes up very limited aspects of the patient’s pathway through the health care system. A patient’s treatment is not only dependent on their socio-economic status, place of residence i.e. place of work (urban or rural area) or their type of illness (acute, chronic) but is also influenced by a multitude of other factors (e.g. age and sex). 269 Kraßnitzer, H. (2006). ″ Vienna: Accessing the physician practice without barriers.″ Medical Tribune, Ärztemagazin 17, accessed at http://www.medicaltribune.at/dynasite.cfm?dssid=4169&dsmid=73550&dspaid=570836 on 09/05/2006 270 Accessed at http://www.gleichstellung.at/rechte/bgstg.php on 17/06/2006 271 Internet without barriers, accessed at http://www.iob.at/ on 16/06/2006 Web Accessibility Initiative, accessed at http://www.w3.org/ on 16/06/2006 272 Christian Schuller (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). 9 June 2006 (via email) LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 93 The following pathways represent ideal pathways, which do not necessarily correspond to the actual pathway or a standardized process. Frequently deviations can and will occur which ought to be discussed in the context of the individual situation. No emergency In Austria, in many cases the consultation of a general practitioner is the first contact of a patient with the health system. The patient can choose the physician freely and usually consult him after arranging an appointment (specialist). Sometimes the general practitioner asks patients to come during his office hours without prior notice. Until recently the patient had to claim a health insurance voucher from his employer before consulting a physician (a general practitioner, a specialist or a dentist). For each voucher he had to pay a fee of €3.63 (2005). For the insured population of the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA) or the Insurance fund of the civil servants this was not necessary (they received a certain amount of health insurance vouchers by mail). Pensioners also had their insurance vouchers sent to their homes and were exempt from the fee. However with the introduction of the e-card (electronic health care voucher) this procedure has become obsolete for the majority of the insured. Sometimes treatment for the patient is already completed after the appointment at the GP. If the illness is treated by means of medication the patient usually goes to the pharmacy closest to him and receives the medication by presenting the prescription issued for him by the physician. In some cases a checkup at the GP within a certain time period may be necessary to assess treatment progress. Under certain circumstances it is essential that the patient, in the course of clarification of his diagnosis or therapy obtains further medical statements from specialists or other diagnostic institutions (laboratories, institutes). He is referred to these by his GP; the reason of the referral must be stated on the referral note (this is currently still a slip of paper). It is quite common that the GP recommends a certain specialist to the patient. Points of first access for patients are, next to general practitioners, also paediatricians (GP for children), gynaecologists (for women), dentists and ophthalmologists. Individuals working in larger companies frequently use the company physician’s services available to them. In the Austrian health care system the patient is entitled to directly (without referral from the GP) access a specialist, an outpatient department of a hospital or an ambulatory clinic. The patient is obliged to display his e-card. Direct access is not granted to all specialists (e.g. radiologists, laboratory physicians, doctors of physical medicine only with restrictions). The insured is limited to the use of one specialist of the same specialty within a quarter of a year (when seeking reimbursement of treatment through social health insurance). Exceptions are granted but require a prior claim by the insured. Direct consultations of specialists (without referral from a GP) have increased considerably in the past; the number of referrals has gone down. After consulting a specialist and completing treatment the therapy in the ambulatory setting is sometimes already concluded. On occasions a final check up at the specialist (e.g. after performing laboratory tests) or at the GP may be required. If the patient needs an elective medical intervention in hospital, the ambulatory doctor completes a hospitalisation note for the patient.273 In case treatment in a hospital is not necessary, but medical treatment is, yet the option of care at home is not provided, this has to be specifically stated on the hospitalisation note. In principal the patient should, according to regulations in the general contract with social health insurance, be transferred to the closest hospital providing the appropriate care. In practice the physician tries to take individual patient’ requests into consideration. The hospital in which the patient is ultimately treated (at least for patients without private health insurance) is chosen based on available bed capacity. The referring physician usually clarifies if the hospital has a free bed for his patient. 273 In principle any physician can write a hospitalisation note, equally any outpatient-department LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 94 Depending on distance, transportation into hospital should generally take place by means of public transport. The use of an ambulance is only permitted in cases medically justified, the necessity has to be certified by the contract doctor. Upon arrival the hospital contacts the patient’s health insurance fund to confirm if it will cover the expenses resulting from the treatment (insurance coverage enquiry). Before discharge of the patient, when inpatient care is no longer medically induced, the attending physician writes a note of discharge as well as a letter of discharge. The latter is for the referring physician or the physician responsible for future treatment so that he can perform any necessary treatment following discharge. It should provide details as well as recommendations related to future treatment. Moreover give instructions for any health care professionals (e.g. nurses) involved. After clarification with the patient the physician letter is given to him personally or sent to either his family doctor or any institution or other health care professional in charge of further treatment and care (by mail or email). Patients may be discharged from hospital in order to be admitted to another hospital, provided that the transferral is necessary and granted. The transferral is executed by an ambulance organization in an ambulance vehicle (responsibility of the municipality or private companies) which is notified by the hospital. In case the patient requires further care after discharge i.e. cannot be left to himself, hospitals are, according to the law (§ 24 KAKuG), obliged to get in touch with public welfare organizations in due time before discharge. Discharge management in hospitals varies considerably in its specifications and intensity. There is a considerable lack in continuity of care, especially for patients who require more extensive care such as chronically ill patients. Some health insurance funds274 employ “care coordinators” who are notified before the patient’s discharge and help the patient to prepare for the time after his inpatient stay (giving information on benefits of social health insurance, medication therapy, etc.). Emergency One of the options in case of an emergency is that the patient himself calls the ambulance (i.e. the radio service for doctors/ doctors’ emergency service during weekends or on holidays. After talking to a doctor on the telephone, the decision is taken for the appropriate means of transport. Alternatively, in case the patient falls ill, the family doctor (general practitioner, specialist) can arrange an admission into hospital by ambulance for the patient. If the patient is not able to call an ambulance himself he is picked up by an emergency ambulance which is usually notified by somebody else. The following procedures can vary in the different federal states. Here the approach in Vienna is described. The emergency ambulance picks up the patient (having been informed about his sex and a possible diagnosis), checks on his condition and performs necessary documentation work. In Vienna a paramedic calls the control station/ central reception for bed availability to inform them about the type of bed required. He receives a case number whilst bed availability is checked. The patient may state personal preferences; however these can only be taken into consideration if the respective hospital has a free bed. If the ambulance does not secure a bed beforehand the hospital may reject the patient upon arrival. When arriving at the hospital the patient is seen by the doctor in charge for admissions/ the doctor on duty. The paramedic gives the doctor the case number and describes the case. Consequently the doctor either decides where the patient is taken or still examines him personally. Afterwards the patient is transferred to the ward. Depending on the type of emergency the decision of the ambulance care used is taken (with respect to staff and medical equipment). On demand an emergency physician can be sent to the place of accident at a later 274 Regional sickness fund for Styria, Insurance fund of the Austrian Mining- and railway Industry LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 95 stage. In the event of an accident, before transferring the patient, a consultation with the central reception has to take place in order to clarify if the accident/emergency ward of a hospital is open or not. If a patient comes to the hospital in a condition of emergency the hospital is not allowed to reject him but is legally obliged to at least provide first aid. Afterwards a transferral to another hospital may be arranged. There are a range of companies offering patient transport ambulance services. The person placing the call decides which company to notify. Transportation expenses are, depending on the diagnosis for transportation, covered either by the social health insurance fund, privately or, in the event of a transferral, by the transferring hospital. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 96 4. REGULATION OF THE HEALTH SYSTEM The past couple decades have witnessed a substantial growth in the volume of new regulatory mechanisms in the health sector. These have largely been a response to the needs of both intentionally and unintentionally generated entrepreneurial activities such as the ‘purchaser-provider split’ in England in the 1990s, choice of sickness fund in Germany and the Netherlands, and reformed payment mechanisms such as global budgets and DRGs for hospitals. It has proven incredibly difficult for governments to design effective regulation, in large part due to the mix of values as well as technical issues that underline regulatory decisions. Due to the complexity in conceptual and technical terms, there is no standard definition of regulation and no standard accepted rationale for introducing regulation. However, there is broad agreement about the source and general mechanisms of regulation.275 These mechanisms can be grouped into two broad categories: tools and strategies. Among the tools include legislation, administrative decree, guidelines, and emergency measures; the strategies refer to the use to which the tools are put. Some potential regulatory strategies are: • • • • • • • • Command-and-control; Self-regulation and enforced self-regulation; Incentive-based regimes (e.g. taxes and subsidies); Market-harnessing controls (e.g. competition laws, franchising, contracts); Disclosure regulation; Direct governmental action; Legal rights and liabilities; and Public compensation/social insurance schemes.276 And beyond tools and strategies there is the important but difficult process of implementation. Within health systems, there are two different possible public purposes for introducing regulation: social and economic policy objectives; and health sector management mechanisms. Within the former include: equity and justice; social cohesion; economic efficiency; health and safety; informed and educated citizens; and individual choice. Within the latter include regulating quality and effectiveness, patient access, provider behaviour, payers, pharmaceuticals, and physicians.277 A wide range of bodies can be involved in regulations: the legislature and government; other governmental, quasi- and non-governmental actors; regional or local authorities (e.g. Land in Germany); and selfregulatory private-sector entities such as the medical profession. A continuum of state authority and supervision can be observed, ranging from the command-and control approach characterised by entities with full state ownership (e.g. hospital directly managed by the health service) and a range of steer-and-channel regulation. Within the more arms-length approach of the latter, there are many possibilities, ranging from: • • • Entities with full state ownership but managerially independent (e.g. NHS trusts in the United Kingdom; public hospitals in Austria and Germany); Private not-for-profit entities with statutory responsibilities (e.g. sickess funds) Private not-for-profit entities without statutory responsibilities (e.g. not-for-profit hospitals in Belgium, Germany, the Netherlands); 275 R.B Saltman and R Busse, "Balancing Regulation and Entrepreneurialism," in Regulating Entrepreneurial Behaviour in European Health Care Systems, ed. R.B Saltman, R Busse, and E Mossialos (Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe, 2002). 276 R Baldwin and M Cave, Understanding Regulation: Theory, Strategy and Practice (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999). 277 Saltman and Busse, "Balancing Regulation and Entrepreneurialism." LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 97 • • Private for-profit providers with continuous service relationships with the public payers (e.g. office-based specialists in Germany, for-profit hospitals contracted by public payers in Italy and Portugal); to Private for-profit companies (e.g. pharmaceutical companies, private insurance companies). 4.1 Performance indicators One possible strategy within health sector regulation is collecting performance indicators and, in some cases, making these publicly available. Performance data that is released to the public arguably serves to: increase public accountability of health care organizations, professionals and managers; and to maintain standards and improve quality.278 There are several assumptions underlying this argument that may or may not be met in practice: • • • • • Patients make rational choices Information asymmetry between purchasers/providers/patients is minimal or, at least, not highly influential Purchasers contract on quality (including safety) not just price Providers respond to a reduction in patients by improving quality instead of cream-skimming That there is a direct relationship between strategies of care and outcomes Evidence that reporting performance to the public improves quality is mixed. The evidence suggests that in some countries patients do not routinely use performance data to choose providers (Denmark, some in the US). However, early evidence from the US, Denmark and New Zealand suggests providers respond to publicly reported performance data. And recent evidence from the US shows that some purchasers are using information on performance to incentivise providers when negotiating contracts.279 It is important to consider the country context when evaluating the success of a regulatory mechanism. For instance, in Denmark national reporting at the provider level was introduced in an attempt to standardize care nationally for six disease groups.280 In the Netherlands, national reporting of individual insurers and providers was intended to simulate payer and provider competition, and patient choice. Finally in Canada and New Zealand, national reporting of province/regional levels served to improve public accountability, and thereby incentivise provider performance on certain indicators such as waiting times. Table 4.1 describes some of the efforts underway in several countries to collect performance data from the insurance, provider and hospital level and release that information to the public. The Danish indicator project was established in 2000 as a mandatory, multidisciplinary quality improvement project to improve care in six disease groups nationwide: stroke, hip fracture, acute surgery, schizophrenia, heart failure, lung cancer, and diabetes. They measured quality of care at unit, county, national and international levels. In terms of public reporting, they found that provider organizations are sensitive and responsive to published information; that quality reports act as a catalyst for activities; and that it is associated with improved processes and outcomes of care. The evaluators of this project concluded that the publication of performance data is professionally accepted when coupled to audit comments; can 278 M. N. Marshall et al., "Public Reporting on Quality in the United States and the United Kingdom," Health Affairs 22, no. 3 (2003). 279 A.M. Epstein, T.H. Lee, and M.B. Hamel, "Paying Physicians for High-Quality Care," The New England Journal of Medicine 350, no. 4 (2004), N.I. Goldfarb et al., "How Does Quality Enter into Health Care Purchasing Decisions?," (New York: The Commonwealth Fund, 2003), Jan Mainz et al., "Nationwide Continuous Quality Improvement Using Clinical Indicators: The Danish National Indicator Project," International Journal for Quality in Health Care 16, no. S1 (2004). 280 Mainz et al., "Nationwide Continuous Quality Improvement Using Clinical Indicators: The Danish National Indicator Project." LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 98 enhance improvement activities; has clear effects on priority setting; yet lacks any impact on patient empowerment.281 Table 4.1 Countries that collect and release Insurance funds/regional authorities United States Comparative performance of health care insurance plans is publicly available The Netherlands Denmark New Zealand France Canada performance indicators to the public Health care Hospitals providers In 2005, the Safety-related reporting, Ambulatory care such as adverse incidents Quality Alliance and hospital acquired selected a ‘starter set’ infection rates. Hospitals of 26 clinical voluntarily report data on performance measure indicators of the quality of for the ambulatory care for acute myocardial care setting. infarction, congestive heart failure and pneumonia. Information on contents, Information on prices, The Dutch inspector for prices and services are quality and waitinghealth care (IGZ) has collected. times are collected. developed a data-set on the quality of Dutch hospitals. It is now working on a minimum set of demands. Information about the performance of, and quality of care provided by, health plans, hospitals, primary care groups and nursing homes is freely available. Publicly disclosed Waiting times for surgery information is at regional and cancer treatment. and sub-regional levels. Key outcomes, e.g. improved health (particularly chronic disease management), and reducing inequalities, are collected Performance data from A technical Agency for public and private Information on Hospital providers is mandatory Care (ATIH) was recently and publicly disclosed set up to manage the through accreditation information reports. Providers are systematically collected evaluated on several from all hospital stays. dimensions including quality of care, information given to the patient, medical records, general management, risk prevention strategies. Data for an agreed set of indicators on health status, health outcomes and quality 281 Jan Mainz and Paul D. Bartels, "Nationwide Quality Improvement--How Are We Doing and What Can We Do?," International Journal for Quality in Health Care 18, no. 2 (2006). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 99 Germany of service from the provinces/territories are reported in a central public website. Regional authorities use performance data to identify low- and highperforming hospitals. In 2007, Germany will begin a national quality benchmarking project in ambulatory care. The 2001 national benchmarking program monitors the safety and quality of care in hospitals; quality of care for 26 conditions or procedures, using 10-15 evidence-based indicators for each. Data are collected electronically and shared among participants. 4.2 Regulating the health system in Austria Austrian’s Social Insurance system is characterised by various models of health care provision which are defined by the relationship between the social health insurance fund and the health care provider. Not only are there integrated providers (in Austria these are called “proprietary/own institutions of social insurance”) but also contractual relationships with various providers of health care services. Direct reimbursement of providers also takes place, mainly in the context of a partial refund paid by social insurance to the insured for services consumed at providers who have not signed a contract with social health insurance. Integrated provision of care – institutions of social insurance Social insurance funds provide health care services to their insured population, in accordance with existing legal regulations, in both their own inpatient and outpatient institutions/clinics. These institutions are fully integrated with respect to supply and reimbursement. Institutions of the insurance funds are ambulatories, accident hospitals, spas and rehabilitation clinics. In the field of inpatient care social insurance funds operate one general hospital (Vienna regional sickness) with 468 beds, seven accident/emergency hospitals (AUVA) with 916 beds, 30 hospitals providing specialised care (primarily in the area of rehabilitation) (Sonderkrankenanstalten) with 4,049 beds, 12 sanatoria with 986 beds and 5 convalescent and recreation homes with 525 beds.282 Details on regional distribution of these can be found in Appendix 7. In the ambulatory setting social insurance funds run 159 outpatient clinics (46 general specialist outpatient clinics, 82 outpatient clinics for dental care and 31 institutions for preventive services and other institutions).283 Contractual relationships Relations between health insurance funds and their contractual partners are regulated by contracts (under private law) and in laws (sixth part of the General Social Security Act, hospital laws of the Federation and the federal states). In individual cases always both sources should be consulted. The health insurance funds sign contracts with various health care providers in order to meet their legal obligation to supply their insured population with services in kind. Contractual partners of social insurance are defined as all individual persons or health care institutions providing medical or comparable services on the bill of social 282 283 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, reporting year 2005, published July 2006 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, reporting year 2005, published July 2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 100 insurance, including amongst others doctors, dentists, midwives, pharmacists, truss makers, orthopaedic technicians, psychotherapists, psychologists, hospitals and Patient Transport Ambulance Services. Within Social insurance a distinction is made between general contracts and individual contracts, the first can be either curative or other general contracts. Subject to the condition that the health care provider has a representative lobby (representation of interest i.e. professional organization), initially a general contract is signed284 and at a later stage individual contracts with the single health care providers. In case no general contract is accomplished or if a general contract is cancelled, services for patients are provided as benefits in cash instead of kind, meaning they have to pay when accessing i.e. consuming services. They are entitled to a partial refund by social insurance at a later stage if they send the invoice of the consultation to their sickness fund (80% of contractual tariff). In the event of a situation without a valid general contract (vertragsloser Zustand) all individual contracts loose their validity. For the psychotherapists a special solution was created, as up to today no contract was accomplished with the Hauptverband, whereby the regional sickness funds have signed contracts with the professional associations (Vereine).285 In 2005 Austrian social insurance had 8.145 contract doctors representing 55% of all free-lance doctors286 (4.285 general practitioners and 3.860 specialists) and 2.894 contracts with dentists representing 81% of all free-lance dentists. Details on the number of contract doctors can be found in Appendix 8.287 The signing of an individual contract with social insurance by a health care provider does not result in the creation of an employment status. The provider continues to work on a self-employed basis. Lump sum payments For the hospitals funded by the federal health care agencies (fund-hospitals) the agreement according to article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act is regularly signed by the Federation and the federal states. The new article 15a- agreement which was negotiated between representatives of the Federation and the federal states during the second term in 2004 is valid for 2005-2008 and has the title “organization and funding of the health care system”. In contrast to the Federation and the federal states, whose contributions represent fixed cash payments and fixed percentages of the respective revenue generated by value added tax288, social health insurance funds render a lump sum towards the funding of public hospitals, which is based on § 447 para.1 ASVG and covers all services of hospitals funded by the federal states’ health agencies (Landesgesundheitsfonds) including inpatient care, semi-inpatient services, day-clinical services and services provided in outpatient departments, always taking account for technological advances289. This lump sum covers around 42% of the fund hospitals’ expenditures and is adjusted yearly according to the increase in social insurance contributions. In the year 2005 Social insurance paid 3.384 billion Euros to the federal health agencies.290 Profit-orientated hospitals i.e. sanatoria which are not funded by the federal states’ health care agencies are funded by uniform performance orientated methods. Every year health insurance funds pay a prospective budget of 72.67 million Euros into a fund which was established in 2002 at the Chamber of Commerce, 284 Between the representatives, e.g. the regional Medical Chamber for the doctors working in practices in that federal state and the Hauptverband for the respective sickness fund. 285 „The Hauptverband has to, according to § 597 Abs. 5 ASVG (together with the Federal Association of Psychotherapy) „in preparation for a general contract develop a concept for psychotherapy, which has to include a comprehensive economic cost-benefit analysis. The validity of existing contracts about the delivery of benefits related to psychotherapy is not affected by this.“ The concept was developed by the Institute of Advanced Studies in the course of the project „Concept for Psychotherapy” and analyses the provision of psychotherapeutic care in Austria. The study report is available at the Hauptverband (source: Hauptverband, report for the conference of the insurance funds on 30 November 2005, covering the topic; concept for psychotherapy, further proceedings 286 Excluding dentists 287 Hauptverband (2006). Handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2006. Vienna 288 Tripold, M. (2005). Das österreichische Gesundheitssystem von 1945 bis in die Gegenwart. In Sprenger, M. Eds. (2005). Public Health in Österreich und Europa, Lengerich, Pabst Science Publishers. 289 Services/benefits not covered in the course of the mother-child-pass examinations are services of out-patient care. Furthermore benefits which social insurance and the federal states have explicitly decided to exclude. 290 Hauptverband (2006). Handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2006. Vienna LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 101 (Privatkrankenanstalten-Finanzierungsfonds, PRIKRAF). The above mentioned fund, which is based on a general contract between the Hauptverband and the Chamber of Commerce, includes 48 hospitals.291 Direct payments i.e. refunds by social insurance Insured consulting health care providers who have not signed a contract with social insurance have to pay in cash for the services consumed. After the consultation the insured has the option of sending the invoice to his health insurance fund claiming a partial refund. The cash refunds are usually a maximum of 80% of the costs which would have resulted had the insured accessed a contract provider, reduced by possible user charges payable by the insured. According to the statistics of the Austrian Medical Chamber (December 2005) Austria has 7,312 private, non-contract doctors with a practice. Out of these 2,013 are General Practitioners, 4,526 specialists and 773 dentists.292 The number of consultations of private providers without a contract with social insurance has risen over the past years; nevertheless, for most of the health insurance funds, they hold a share of less than 10% of the total consultations.293 4.2.1 Independent monitoring agencies The Austrian health system does not have an independent supervisory commission that is comparable to the Audit Commission in the UK. The Austrian system is hierarchical whereby duties and responsibilities are primarily defined by law. It is mainly organised in a federal way, not only in the area of social insurance funds but also in hospital care. Depending on the region the sanitary agencies of the federal states may have a range of duties and responsibilities, primarily in the area of hospital care but formally also in the area of community care (physicians in surgeries). The central responsibility in the health system lies with the federation, which assigns it’s duties within the framework of the related federal administration to the federal states or, in form of self-administration, to the social insurance funds. Within the framework of self-administration, the social insurance funds operate free of directives but under the state supervision of the appropriate ministry (see also §§ 448 ff. ASVG). External supervisory bodies of social insurance are, amongst others, the audit board, which is responsible for financial control. The supervisory bodies of the social insurance funds are the Ministry of Health and Women (BMGF) (since 1.05.03, earlier the Ministry of Social Security and Generations) for the national health insurance and accident insurance, as well as, the Ministry of Social Security, Generations and Consumer Protection for the legal pension insurance and the Main Association of Austrian Social Insurance Funds (Hauptverband). The Ministry of Finance protects the financial interests of the federation, is involved in the budgets for hospitals and care facilities, and is the supervisory body of the Main Association of Austrian Social Insurance funds (pension insurance funds). The Ministry of Justice and the Ministry of Defence are carriers of some hospitals, the Ministry of Education, Science and Culture is responsible for securing medical education at the university (human medicine, dentistry). The Ministry of Social Security, Generations and Consumer Protection has the directive over unemployment insurance. Where the regional area of an insurance fund only encompasses a single federal state and does not exceed its boundaries, then the head of that federal state is responsible for the immediate supervision, of health insurance funds only when they have less than 400 000 insured persons.294 291 Hauptverband (2006). Handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2006. Vienna Mag. Sinabell (Austrian Medical Chamber). 23 January 2006. Status December 2005 (via email) 293 Answers of the sickness funds to the questionnaire sent to them in November 2005 294 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 292 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 102 The supervisory bodies have a duty, within their area of responsibility, to ensure that the legal requirements of health care are fulfilled and complied with. In addition they oversee the financial conduct of the insurance funds or the Association of Austrian social Insurance funds and test the expediency of the administration (see §§ 448 ASVG).295 They have the right to veto and the right to inspection. The supervisory bodies have the right to send delegates to meetings of the administrative bodies or the Hauptverband (advisory function and right to veto). Important resolutions require the consent of the supervisory body. It is not the duty of the supervisory body to carry out quality control. Establishment of an independent institute for research and planning – Health Care Austria Plc. On the 20th of April 2006 the Council of Ministers decided on the merger of the Healthy Austria Fund (Fonds Gesundes Österreich, FGÖ) and the Austrian Federal Institute for Health Care (Österreichisches Bundesinstitut für Gesundheitswesen, ÖBIG) to the “Health Care Austria Plc”. The “Federal Institute for Quality in Health Care (Bundesinstitut für Qualität im Gesundheitswesen, BIQG) will also be integrated into the Plc. The decision of parliament was taken on the 23rd of May, accompanied by severe criticism of the opposition. The legal basis is the Federal Law on the Health Care Austria Plc (Bundesgesetz über die Gesundheit Österreich GmbH, GÖGG). According to the Minister of health, Rauch-Kallat, the new company should be an independent national institute for research and planning for the entire health care system.296 The new institute will be responsible for providing the basis for decision-making for structural planning in health care provision as well as for developing guidelines for quality assurance and health care promotion. Duties are regulated in § 4 GÖGG and are divided according to business divisions (division ÖBIG, division BIQG, division FGÖ). Bodies of the Plc. are, based on § 7 ÖGGG, the general assembly, the managing director, the institutional assembly and the board of trustees. Moreover advisory boards are to be established. The company has to nominate a managing director (by means of public advertisement for a max. of 5 years), who may, by decision of the federal minister of health and women, be complemented for a defined limited time period by the prior managing directors of the ÖBIG (until latest 31 May 2009) and the FGÖ (until latest 30 September 2006). The institutional assembly is made up of 27 members originating in equal shares from the Federation, the federal states and Social Insurance (9:9:9). The chair is held by the Federal Minister of Health and Women. Among the members 2 substitutes are elected (from the group of the members of the federal states and from the group of the members of Social Insurance respectively). Already during the phase of assessment the merger of the institutions (ÖBOG, FGÖ, BIQG) was rejected by all sorts of groups involved. Several federal states, the Chamber of Commerce, the Chamber of Labour and the Hauptverband stated their rejection. Especially the choice of the legal form of a Plc. was criticised. 297 The employees of the ÖBIG warned that the costs of the Ltd have been underestimated and that the consequences have not been considered.298The SPÖ and the Green Party voted against the law. The Medical Chamber gave an extremely negative statement. 295 Brodil, W., Windisch-Graetz, M. (2005). Main features of Social Law. Vienna, WUV Universitätsverlag. Federal Ministry of Health and Women 20.04.2006 11:31 Rauch-Kallat: Health Care Austria Plc. Will be a strong institution for research and planning for the health care sector.“, accessed at www.bmgf.gv.at on 30/05/2006 297 Statement of the Chamber of Labour to the Federal Ministry of Health and Women, sent on 7 April, accessed at http://www.konvent.gv.at/pls/portal/docs/page/PG/DE/XXII/ME/ME_00401_42/fname_061366.pdf on 30/05/2006 298 Statement of the ÖBIG-employees regarding the draft of the law by which the Health Care Austria Plc. is brought to life. Accessed at 296 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 103 Doubts are raised in relation to the impartiality of the institute which will be owned by the Federation to 100%. The Plc. will operate completely independent and without being accountable to other institutions (weisungsfrei).299 According to § 14 (1), the company should be managed based on commercial principles (profitability, frugality, fitness for purpose). Work of the ÖQMed will not be affected by the new institute.300 4.2.2 Extent of decentralization of regulatory functions This section describes responsibilities in the Austrian health care system, detailing which actor performs which activities. Furthermore it is discussed if these are implemented by the person/organization himself/themselves or if they are referred to another position/ institution. In case of the latter, information on the type of decentralization is given. A table was chosen as means of presentation in which functions i.e. areas of service provision are assigned the institution responsible for implementation as well as the type of referral of authority applied.301 The examples listed in Table 4.2 are not exhaustive. In the Table 4.2, adapted from a study by Hofmarcher and Rack (2006), the authors describe the main decision-making authorities in the Austrian health care system whereby they distinguish between different areas of services provided. For each area they list the sources of funding, the share of the Austrian health care expenditure consumed (in %) as well as the responsibilities i.e. authorities with regard to the provision, the quality assurance and the reimbursement of the service. The table includes ambulatory-, inpatient and long term care. Responsibilities are either centralised (authority of the Federation), delegated (transferred to lower levels) or given over to higher levels by means of devolution. Deconcentration (the transmission of administrative responsibilities i.e. power to regional authorities which remain accountable towards the higher levels i.e. are subordinate to a higher body) is hardly applied in Austria. Many cases concerning the transferring of duties i.e. decision-making authorities could also be described as regionalization, for instance if these are given to the federal states or the health insurance funds. Numerous functions in the health care system are undertaken by private entities (e.g. private hospitals, welfare institutions, self-help groups, organizational privatization of public hospitals) or by private individuals (e.g. dependants). http://www.parlament.gv.at/pls/portal/docs/page/PG/DE/XXII/ME/ME_00401_04/imfname_060866.pdf, on 30/05/2006 299 Dannhauser, C. (2006). ″Power struggle: turbulences related to the health care Austria Plc.“, Die Presse, 19.05.06, accessed at www.diepresse.com, on 30/052006 300 Ärztemagazin, accessed at http://medical-tribune.at on 30/05/2006 301 Based on table 10 in the Chapter Decentralization of the Austrian’ Health Care in Transition Report 2006 (Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M., 2006). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 104 Table 4.2 Decision-making authority and public funding for different types of services in the Austrian health care system, 2005 Public funding in% of PHEa Social insurance contributions 19.3 11.0 1.2b Type of service Provision General practitioners, Medical specialists, Dentists in their practices, Other health care professionals, Ambulatory clinics Drugs Medical devices Rehabilitation Hospitals including outpatient departments 0.9 Health care promotion Prevention Reimbursement Regionalization, delegation to health insurance funds, Scope for voluntary services of health insurance, partially integrated provision of care Regionalization and delegation to health insurance funds for reimbursable drugs Federal laws Professional bodies including the health insurance funds Delegated to health insurance funds, general contracts determine the individual contracts Federal laws, Authorization of pharmaceuticals, Monitoring, Social insurance Delegated to social insurance funds; Partially integrated provision of care Regionalization; Responsibility of the federal states based on the B-VG and KAKuG; For occupational accidents delegated to social insurance funds and integrated provision of care Federal law Delegated to health insurance funds: reimbursement, pricing negotiations are undertaken by the Hauptverband, Calculation of the average price in the EU (upper price limit), authority of the Federation Delegated to social insurance funds Authority of the Federation and the federal states; partially delegated to social insurance funds Federal Laws: Fund Healthy Austria (Health Care Austria Plc.), partially delegated to the federal states and social insuranced Provisions in federal and regional laws Sanitary control by the Federation; Authorization of the hospitals by the federal states Contributions: 40% Taxes: 60% 41.1 Quality work LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment Day-to day operations: regionalised and delegated to regionally organised funds; Decentral mechanisms of distribution to hospitals (per case payments), subsidies and investments: regionalised, responsibility of the federal states i.e funds Partially delegated to the regional sickness funds, General contracts 105 Taxes 18.3c Public Health Services (e.g. Public Health Officers, social services, environmental medicine) Authority of the Federation, the federal states and the local governments / municipalities Long-term care Federal states Private providers Dependants (informal care) Federal and regional laws, in terms of organization mostly delegated to the federal states, further transferral to the local authorities Regional laws for nursing homes Devolution to the federal states Further transferral to the local authorities (local sanitary authority) Decentralised allocation of the nationally uniform cash benefit (based on need) – long term care allowance - by the pension insurance funds B-VG=Law of the Federal Constitution (Federal Constitutional Act), KAKuG= Federal law for hospitals and convalescent homes a PHE=Public health expenditure: including federal cash allowances for long-term care, 2003 b only medical rehabilitation in health insurance c including expenditures of the federal states for health promotion d health promotion and prevention strategy of social insurance 2005-2010. 8.3 Sources: IHS Health Econ 2005; Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. In the health care system a great variety of methods i.e. instruments are used to exert regulation. The following table lists some of these as well as giving examples of areas of application in the Austrian health care system. The list is exemplary, not exhaustive. Table 4.3 Regulatory instruments in the Austrian health care sector Regulatory instrument Examples of health care regulations - Legislation/ command and control - Self regulation and enforced self regulation - Incentives - Establishment/ Authorization/Extension of health care institutions Training-/ Eduction provisions, -requirements Sanitary control of health care institutions Obligations for documentation Obligation to report (communicable diseases) Social insurance contributions Requirements for statutory insurance Obligation to treat Social insurance (e.g. collection of contributions, Filling of free posts as contract partners for social health insurance) Quality control of community physicians by ÖQMed Continuing further education for doctors and other health care professionals, e.g. pharmacists (representative bodies, Chambers) Partially on the level of Municipalities/ Districts, to encourage doctors to work in structurally disadvantaged areas Subsidies of health insurance funds when introducing/implementing new IT Various subsidies for establishment of barrier free access Incentives of health insurance funds in the general contract i.e. the fee structure, e.g. performing some additional training in order to bill certain services with the health insurance fund LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 106 - Market harnessing - Disclosure - Direct Action - Rights and liabilities - Compensation - Free choice of doctor Fees of private health care providers Private health insurance Hospital associations Quality reporting302 Surveys on patient satisfaction Health care information centres (e.g. of some health insurance funds Development of guidelines and treatment pathways by specialist associations (of medical specialties) or health insurance funds Advertisment and allocation of free posts with social health insurance Websites (of health care providers, e.g. of hospitals) Licensing of medication Price range for medicines Education/ Training related matters Public Health Health care planning Monitoring institutions (hygiene) Quality assurance303 Contribution of the Federation for Social Insurance (SVAgW, SVB) Patient Charta Contracts with health care providers (z.B. General contract with physicians) Disagreement register for organ donations Obligation to report (statutory insurance, adverse side-effects of medication, communicable diseases) Obligation for continuous education and training Obligation to treat emergencies Obligation to treat based on general contract Medical error (liability insurance, extra-judical agreement) Accident insurance (Integrity compensation / Integritätsabgeltung gem. § 213 a ASVG) 4.2.3 Regulating purchasing The Fiscal Constitution law (Finanz-Verfassungsgesetz) composes the general framework of the financial relationship between the Federation, the federal states and the local governments (municipalities). It states that the regulation and collection of taxes is primarily to be performed by Federation, the revenue is distributed among the Federation, the nine federal states and the communities according to the Financial Equalization Act (Finanzausgleichsgesetz). The latter defines that each local/regional authority has to in principle cover its own expenses. Furthermore it enables central government to allocate rights of taxation and defines that the performance of the local/regional authorities is to be considered in the context of the financial equalization.304 Another significant legal foundation for the system of funding, particularly for inpatient care, pertaining an important co-ordinating function is the agreement reached between the Federation and the federal states pursuant to article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act. This agreement is negotiated on a regular basis (every 4 years). 302 Not yet published by the BMGF (Federal Ministry of Health and Women) Austrian Federal Institute for Quality Assurance (Bundesinstitut für Qualitätssicherung), in future part of the Health Care Austria Plc. (Gesundheit Austria GmbH) 304 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 303 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 107 Funding within Social insurance is equally regulated by law, namely in the General Social Security Act (ASVG) and in the relevant Social Security Acts for the other professions (Self Employed, Civil servants, Farmers, etc.). These include any regulations related to contributions (§§ 44 ASVG et sqq.) as well as the benefits package of Social health insurance (§§ 116, 117 ASVG). Concerns on reimbursement of health care providers by social insurance are covered in the sixth part of the ASVG, furthermore in contractual arrangements (general contracts, individual contracts, reimbursement schemes, etc.) and other arrangements (for instance Musterkataloge (sample catalogues of benefits) of the Hauptverband). 42% of fund-hospital expenditure is covered by Social health insurance. The funding structure of the socalled fund hospitals between 1996 and 2002 is demonstrated in Figure 4.1. Figure 4.1 Sources of funding for inpatient care – returns of the Austrian fund hospitals, 1996-2002 100% 90% 80% Sonstige 70% Patienten Private KV 60% Rechtsträger 50% Sozialhilfe 40% Gemeinden Land 30% Bund 20% SV 10% 0% 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 SV=Social insurance, Bund= Federation, Land= Federal states, Gemeinden= Local governments/municipalities, Sozialhilfe= Social welfare, Rechtsträger= hospital carrier, Private KV= Private health insurance, Patienten= Patients, Sonstige= Other Other: mainly payments for medical services provided by one fund-hospital carrier for another or payments between fund-hospitals of the same hospital carrier (Mag. Pazourek, 29/09/2006) Source: Hauptverband, Database „White book“ accessed 30/03/2006 Physician services are mainly funded by social health insurance, partially also by private households (noncontract doctors). The areas of prevention and health promotion are financed by social insurance contributions and by tax payments. Social welfare payments are covered mainly by the federal states and the communities, long term care services by the Federation and the federal states. A budget for private hospitals (PRIKRAF fund) is defined on a regular basis between the Chamber of Commerce (representative of the private hospitals) and the Hauptverband (representative of sickness funds). This fund is used to cover the inpatient services provided for insured in 48 private hospitals.305 Role of government in relation to purchasers The Austrian Constitution regulates that central responsibility for the health care system lies, apart from a few exceptions, with the Federation. Government delegates most of these tasks to the federal states by indirect federal administration arrangements or to Social insurance by way of self governance.306 305 Hauptverband (2006). Handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2006. Vienna LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 108 One of the few areas for which central government does not assume total responsibility is in the hospital sector. Here the basic law is defined by the Federation; the regional states are in charge of enacting and implementing it whilst central government accounts for sanitary supervision (see Article 12 B-VG). Legislation and implementation of laws in Social Insurance is, according to Article 10, paragraph 1 Z of the Federal Constitutional Act, responsibility of central government. Organization is, as already mentioned before, carried out by means of self-governance. Central government maintains a certain right of surveillance. Regarding issues of financial equalization the Ministry of Finance is responsible. Furthermore it is supervisory body of the Hauptverband (the pension funds). The Austrian Court of Audit and the tax authorities perform external controls. The legal basis within Social insurance represents the General Social Insurance Act (ASVG) as well as the Social Insurance laws for professions other than the employed. As already indicated all issues related to contributions are covered in the above stated legal documents in great depth. The basic legislation concerning social welfare is the authority of central government, enacting legislation is responsibility of the federal states, whereby social welfare is partially completely assigned to the federal states’ sphere of competence (Art. 15B-VG). Activities of private health insurance companies are subject to control of the Financial Market Authority. Budgets of purchasing organizations Funds of the Federation are generated by tax revenue and are, as already mentioned before, divided between the Federation, the nine federal states and the communities according to the terms stated in the financial equalization Act. Financial resources in social insurance are not distributed by a central fund but are generated primarily by income-based contributions of the insured population. Austria has 21 insurance funds (9 regional funds, 7 occupational funds, the Insurance Fund of the Austrian Railway and Mining Industry307, the Social Insurance Fund of the Farmers, the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business308, the Insurance Fund of the Civil Servants and the Insurance Fund of the Austrian Notaries). Each fund is responsible for the collection of the contributions of its insured population.309 Austrian Social insurance is funded by various sources. Insurance contributions310, amount to 81.0%, the share of the Federation represents 11.0% and other revenues came up to 8.0% (allowances for income support (Ausgleichszulage), other allowances, cost sharing, etc.). 311 In the year 2005 the effective returns of Social Insurance added up to around 39.374 billion Euros. The Austrian Social insurance system is a pay-as-you-go system. Resources needed during a certain period of time are funded by contributions generated in the same time period. The insured does not finance his personal services but contributes solidarity to the funding of the whole system. The pay-as-you-go system facilitates solidarity equalization between healthy and ill (mainly health insurance, accident-, pension insurance) as well as between generations (pension insurance), referred to as the generation contract.312 Furthermore between men and women as well as insured without dependants and insured with dependants. 306 ibid Merger of the Insurance fund of the Austrian Railway Industry with the Insurance Fund of the Austrian Mining Industry in 2005 308 the merger of the Social Insurance Fund of the Farmers with the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA) is currently taking place and should be finalised by the beginning of the year 2007. 309 Partially transfer payments (Kostenersätze) are made between the different types of funds (health insurance and accident insurance) 310 Including contributions of the equalization fund for the pension insurance funds. 311 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2006). Handbook of Austrian Social insurance 2005. Vienna 312 Tomandl, T. (2005). What you always wanted to know about Social Insurance. Vienna, Manz. 307 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 109 Figure 4.2 Sources of income in social insurance, 2005 8% 11% Insurance contributions Federal government Other income 81% Source: Statistical handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2006 The Federation renders a contingent liability (Ausfallshaftung) in pension insurance, provided that the contributions of the insured do not cover all the expenses. With the self-employed, Federation substitutes the employer and pays the difference between the own contribution and the total sum. The state subsidy also covers any deficit caused by people changing insurance funds313 or financial resources for substitute qualifying periods314 which are not met by third parties as well as expenses for granting compensatory allowances for reduced earnings. With accident insurance the federal state covers part of the contributions of the insured of the Farmers sickness fund. In social health insurance close to 83% of the income is made up of insurance contributions (out of this roughly 47.2 % for employed, 5% for self-employed, 1.7% for unemployed, 22.6% for pensioners and 1.0% for voluntarily insured) and about 5% are generated through additional contributions (for dependants in health insurance). About 4.3% are generated by additional contributions (in health insurance, for dependants). 315 When collecting contributions sickness funds are quite frequently confronted with the problem that contributions are either paid too late or are uncollectible. If contributions were paid duly this could result in a surplus for the sickness funds instead of being confronted with a deficit. Only in the 2005 the regional sickness funds had to amortise 155 million Euro as uncollectible contributions, representing about the fivefold amount of the total deficit the sickness funds made (31.7 million Euros). To improve the payment behaviour one is thinking of increasing interests for delay.316 Private health insurance companies fund their services by means of the contributions of their insured population. The market is dominated by few (8) market participants. UNIQA held a share of nearly 50% in 2004, Wiener Städtische of about 20%, Merkur and Generali each a little bit more or less than 13%. The remaining private health insurers each occupy shares of less than 3%. The largest items in terms of expenditure are payments for hospitals, dental care and physician services.317 313 Equalization payments in pension insurance if a person changes his insurance fund times for raising children, for the care of relatives, for unemployment, for military service 315 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2006). Statistisches Handbuch der österreichischen Sozialversicherung 2006. Wien 316 Kurier, 25.04.06, health insurance funds in debt, accessed at http://www.kurier.at/wirtschaft/1348273.php, on 26/04/2006 No author (2006). ″Sickness funds – lost contributions.″ Ärztemagazin 17:2006, accessed at http://www.medical-tribune.at/dynasite.cfm?dssid=4169&dsmid=73550&dspaid=570851 on 09/09/2006 317 Association of private insurance companies (Versicherungsverband Österreich) (2006). Yearly Report 2005. Accessed at www.vvo.at, on 27/04/2006 314 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 110 Private households cover around 27% of health care expenditure, out of which about 57% are indirect user charges and 43% are direct user charges.318 Expenditures of private households include expenses for inpatient care, ambulatory care, medical products, appliances and equipment.319 Risk pooling or revenue sharing arrangements In Austrian Social Insurance various instruments for financial equalization are adopted, not only between the different branches of insurance (health-, accident-, pension insurance), but also between the different funds. The intention of these systems is to promote co-ordination between the funds as well as equalization. The Hauptverband is in charge of equalising and distributing financial resources. Before describing two of the equalization funds used in health insurance in detail it is important to state that these equalizations funds only dispose over minor amounts of financial resources, which obviously reduces the equalization effect obtained. Equalization fund of the regional sickness funds320 The equalization fund of the regional sickness funds should, according to § 447a ASVG guarantee an equal financial performance i.e. liquidity of the regional sickness funds and render payments to the funds in accordance with the available financial resources and the legal definitions. Originally the equalization fund included all health insurance funds which were considered relevant due to their size (the insurance fund of the Austrian Mining Industry, the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business, the Social Insurance Fund of the Farmers (from 1.1.2001), the Insurance Fund of the Civil Servants (from 1.1.2003), the Insurance Fund of the Austrian Railway Industry (from 1.1.2003). In March 2004 the Constitutional Court ruled that the equalization fund as well as regulations on the equalization of structural differences and agreements on goals were partially not compatible with the Constitution. Due to this the respective regulations were abolished. The equalization fund was unconstitutional because it caused a disadvantage inherent to the system i.e. favoured individual sickness funds. Because of higher contribution rates i.e. additional sources of revenue (e.g. user charges) individual sickness funds assumed an above average burden through the mechanism of the equalization fund. Sickness funds experiencing a comparably favourable financial situation were put at a disadvantage not only with respect to the contributions into the fund but also with respect to the transfer payments of the fund. The Constitutional Court decided that the inclusion of the following sickness funds violates the basic equality right and thereby is unconstitutional: Insurance Fund of the Civil Servants, Insurance fund of the Austrian Railway Industry, Insurance Authority for Business (SVA), Social Insurance Fund of the Farmers.321 318 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 319 Statistics Austria, accessed at www.statistik.at, on 27/04/2006 320 § 447a und § 447b ASVG, 1483 of the appendices to the stenographical protocols of the National Asssembly XXII. GP Report of the Committee for Labour and Social Affairs on the government draft (Regierungsvorlage) (1408 of appendices): Federal Law changing the General Social Security Act, the Social Security Act of the self-employed, - of the Farmers, -of the civil servants, Unemployment Act 1977 und das Special Support Act (Sonderunterstützungsgesetz) (Law to change Social Security Laws (Sozialrechts-Änderungsgesetz) 2006 – SRÄG 2006), accessed at http://www.parlament.gv.at/pls/portal/docs/page/PG/DE/XXII/I/I_01483/fname_063470.pdf on 21/06/2006 321 Holzweber, D. (2004). ″Re-organization of the health care insurance funding unconstitutional.″ Soziale Sicherheit 4, pp. 126-127 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 111 The regional sickness funds and the sickness funds of the miners still remained part of the equalization fund. In the year 2005 a restructuring of the equalization fund was agreed upon, based on the result of a project headed by the regional sickness fund of Salzburg which aimed at formulating a scientific model for the structural equalization between the regional sickness funds in the context of the regional equalization fund. The funding of the regional sickness funds’ equalization fund which is situated at the Hauptverband remains the same and takes place by: 1. Insurance contributions of the regional sickness funds– 2% of the income generated by the regional funds through insurance contributions according to § 447 a para.3 ASVG 2. A lump sum according to § 1 para.2 GSBG322 3. Contributions according to § 3 DAG323 4. Revenues on assets (Vermögenserträgnisse) 5. Other revenues The additional income generated by tobacco tax is transferred to the equalization fund by the Minister of Finance. Two thirds of the sum are forwarded to the equalization fund for hospital financing (§ 447f), one third goes towards the fund for preventive services and health care promotion (§ 447h). 10% of the equalization fund’s yearly revenue is allocated to a reserve which is only to be used for the coverage of extraordinary expenses. Revenues of the equalization fund should, apart from very few exceptions, be distributed to four areas whereby the conference of the sickness funds (Trägerkonferenz) has defined the distribution between respective areas. For the year 2005, after deducting the earmarked financial resources for administration of a general hospital (30 million Euro), 45% of the remaining sum are used for structural equalization, 45% for equalization of liquidity and 10% for meeting special equalization demands. The distribution of financial resources of the equalization fund to the regional sickness funds follows diverging regulations. The resources of the equalization fund are, according to § 447a para.6 ASVG, to be used for equalization of different structures, different liquidity and for covering special equalization needs. The equalization of structural differences is performed based on § 447b ASVG, the equalization of liquidity is based on the net assets of each insured entitled to access services and the coverage of a special equalization need is met based on a defined distribution key. Risk equalization (§ 447 para.1 ASVG) not only considers the revenue generated by contributions and by the prescription charge but also the average cost for each insured (by age and sex) as well as for insured who cause extraordinarily high costs. In addition to these aspects certain supply related factors such as regional burdens are taken into consideration. Moreover burden resulting from the funding of hospitals based on § 447f. ASVG. Equalization fund for hospital financing Within the scope of the equalization fund for hospital financing, according to § 447f, the sickness funds (all but the insurance fund of the Austrian Notaries) pay a lump sum for hospital services324 to the health care 322 323 Law for subsidies for health care and social care (Gesundheits- und Sozialbereich-Beihilfengesetz) Employer payments Act (Dienstgeberabgabegesetz) LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 112 agencies established in the federal states (Landesgesundheitsfonds). The size of the lump sum is negotiated on a regular basis in the course of the negotiations on hospital financing related to the article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act. Every year the sum is adjusted according to the increase in insurance contributions. The equalization fund for hospital financing has been administered by the Hauptverband since 1978. Financial transfers to the health care agencies of the federal states are executed in partial amounts, the height of the payable amounts as well as the initial financial resources paid into the agency by the health insurers is regulated by a predefined distribution key. The capital of the agency is generated by an additional health insurance contribution as well as supplementary transfers of the sickness funds (based on a distribution key). According to the financial equalization Act, additional financial resources for hospitals in the period of 2005-2008 will be generated by increasing the contribution rate by 0.1%, by using income from tobacco tax and by increasing the earning limit for chargeable contributions. For the 48 private hospitals a fund was established at the Chamber of Commerce (representing the private Hospitals and spa-institutions) in 2002, the so-called PRIKRAF Fund. It covers private hospitals with beds which are not funded by the funds of the federal states. The PRIKRAF Fund represents a yearly lump sum payment of the sickness funds of around 72.7 million Euros. 325 Further equalization instruments A further equalization instrument is the “calculation group pension insurance” (Rechenkreis Pensionsversicherung), which is in charge of the orderly processing of transfer payments to the pension insurance funds made via the Hauptverband. The group is made up of all pension insurance funds apart from the insurance fund of the Austrian Notaries. In addition to the just described equalization mechanisms an equalization fund for the distribution of the financial burden of the sickness funds related to expenses for hospital care (obstetric care) was introduced. The legal basis is § 322a ASVG. This fund was established to compensate any unequal burden of sickness funds arising through increases in insurance contributions, when paying the lump sum for hospital services. Another fund is the fund for preventive services and health care promotion, according to § 447h ASVG which is used for preventive services as well as measures of health promotion co-ordinated by the Hauptverband. 4.3.5 Regulating provision Health services for the care of the general public are, to a large extent publicly funded, mainly through contributions of social insurance fund and tax money from the federation. Services are rendered by the state, private non-profit organizations, and private individuals or organizations. The legal foundations in which responsibilities in health care are defined are the Federal Law for Hospitals and Clinics (Bundesgesetz für Kranken- und Kuranstalten), the corresponding federal state laws, the General Social Insurance Law (Allgemeines Sozialversicherungsgesetz) as well as the special laws in social insurance (GSVG, B-KUVG, BSVG, FSVG). Furthermore, agreements between the federation and the federal states, above all the agreement according to Art. 15a B-VG, currently effective for the period 2005-2008, are highly pertinent to hospitals. Fundamentally, almost all areas of the health care system are assigned to the expertise of the federation, with the exception of hospitals. Here the federation provides the framework 324 The lump sum and cost-sharing of insured covers all services in hospitals used by insured or their dependants, specifically inpatient services, semi-inpatient services, day clinic and ambulatory hospital services. Thereby taking medical progress into consideration. 325 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB (2006). Handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2005, Vienna. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 113 (KAKuG, Österreichischer Strukturplan Gesundheit, etc.), the responsibility for implementation lies with the federal states. In general the federation does not carry out all the duties itself, but delegates many duties to other players in the health system. In Austria social insurance plays a central role when it comes to the provision of medical services for the general public. Organised as a form of self-administration, the insurance community or rather its representatives (divisions) are assigned numerous fields of expertise by the federation, such as the collection of contributions or the negotiation of contracts with service providers. Through the signing of contracts (general or individual) under private law directly with service providers or their legal representatives, the social insurance assures area-wide medical care. In addition it has, in some areas, (e.g. clinics, hospitals) its own facilities which supplement the network of contract partners. Statutory health insurance must, in accordance with § 116 ASVG, ensure the provision of certain services. The range of services can be voluntarily extended through the statutes (Satzungen) of the health insurance funds. The service commitment or rather the range thereof is based on the recommendations of the Supreme Sanitary Council (Oberster Sanitätsrat) and various internal expert bodies of the social insurance. The final decision rests with the political decision makers.326 Aside from health insurance services, accident insurance (§ 148a ASVG) services and pension insurance (§ 222 ASVG) services also play a role in the provision of medical care. The Contractual partners of social insurance are doctors, i.e., general practitioners and specialists (in 2005 8,145 or 55% of freelance doctors327 had contracts with the social health insurance328) and dentists (on 31.12.2005 2,936 dentists had a contractual relationship with social insurance, that is equivalent to 81% of freelance dentists).329 Beyond this, contractual partners include clinical psychologists and psychotherapists, pharmacists, hospitals (socalled fund-hospitals330, private hospitals and convalescent institutions), rehabilitation centres, orthopaedic shoemakers, hearing aid acousticians and midwives. In the field of hospital care it is, according to federal law (KAKuG), the duty of the federal states to assure hospital care for the general public. The federation is responsible for policy legislation, the federal states for execution legislation. This area of responsibility encompasses the construction and operation of public hospitals or the completion of agreements with legal representatives from other hospitals to ensure institutional care. The federal states must see to it that sufficient beds are available at standard tariff rates (in the general wards) for those people requiring inpatient care. Capacity planning at federal state level must be carried out in consultation with federal planning (Austrian structure plan for health (Österreichischer Strukturplan Gesundheit), formerly the Austrian hospitals and equipment plan) or rather, must follow its guidelines. Provision of services in the field of public health (vaccinations, health care, health promotion, counselling (amongst others for pregnant women, HIV sufferers)), as well as, social services and long term care services is assured primarily by the federal states, and in part by local authorities and/or social health insurance. Public health activities, above all, concentrate on sanitary control, provision of expert opinions and the development of health promotion and prevention programs. Social insurance also provides measures for health promotion; here the periodic health examinations (precautionary health examinations, juvenile examinations) are inherently significant. Federal state health bodies (Landesgesundheitsplattformen) were likewise allocated health promotion and prevention functions within the scope of the health reform 2005. Furthermore, the implementation of health promotion measures was assigned to the Healthy Austria Fund (Fonds Gesundes Österreich, FGÖ) within the framework of the Health Promotion Law (Gesundheitsförderungsgesetz). 326 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 327 excl. dentists 328 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB (2006). Handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2005, Vienna. 329 ibid 330 These are funded by the funds of the Federal Health Agencies in the federal states LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 114 The Federal Nursing Allowance Law (Bundespflegegeldgesetz, BGBI. Nr. 110/93) passed in July 1993, together with the nine regional Nursing Allowance Laws (Landespflegegeldgesetze) form the legal basis for precautionary or preventive care (long term care). The Federal Nursing Allowance Law also regulates claims to non-cash care benefits for long term care. “The federal states commit themselves to a decentralised and area-wide construction and expansion of out-patient services, part in-patient and inpatient social services in consideration of minimum standards”.331 In addition the federal states are responsible for the networking332 of these services as well as the provision of information and counselling. The federation is responsible for the protection of individuals requiring long term care by means of social insurance. The field of emergency rescue and recovery is actually, with regards legislation and execution, the concern of the federal states. However the federal states transfer the management of local rescue services (ambulance, first aid) to the regional councils. These, in turn, mostly place contracts with welfare organizations in order to fulfil their allocated duties. Emergency medical assistance is provided by various facilities and organizations within the health system. Hospital out-patient departments and public hospitals play an important role in primary emergency care. Other facilities having a central role in the field of emergency care are rescue organizations. In Austria the rescue and ambulance services are, above all, run by the Austrian Red Cross, besides this, there are other recognised organizations. The responsibility for the national rescue and ambulance services lies with the federal states, which can however transfer these duties, by means of contractual agreements, to qualified physical or legal persons. Air rescue falls within the competence of the federation. Primary care Primary care is provided by doctors (general practitioners or specialists) in their own, mainly individual private, practices. A portion of primary care providers operate in group practices333 or community practices. Service providers either have a contract with social insurance (contract doctors or contract group practices) or offer their services privately (private doctors, private group practices). Besides independently practicing doctors there are other facilities for out-patient treatment which are either run by social insurance334 or as private ventures. These include out-patient clinics335, institutes or laboratories. In addition, hospital outpatient departments cover a large portion of primary care. The ownership structures in hospitals are dealt with in the next sections. Health service providers on a par with doctors (e.g. psychologists, psychotherapists, speech therapists, occupational therapists, midwives) operate, like doctors, either as private individual undertakings with or without any contract with social insurance, or are employed by health care establishments (e.g. hospitals). Public health care is provided by public establishments (government health departments of the federal states, health bureaus of the district administrative bodies, public health officers, specialist departments in the communities). 331 Federal Ministry of Social Security, Generations and Consumer protection (2004). Long-term care in Austria.Vienna 332 health and social parish 333 Since 2002 there is the opportunity to set up group practices. Legal basis is given in the second amendment to the doctors law (BGBl. I No. 110/2001) as well as 58th ASVG amendment (BGBl. I Nr. 99/2001) and the parallel amendments to ASVG. 334 In 2005: 46 general specialist outpatient clinics, 82 dental clinics and 31 juvenile and health examination centres and other miscellaneous facilities (source: Hauptverband) 335 Independent outpatient clinics are, according to law, hospitals LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 115 Secondary care In 2005 about half (131) of the 264 hospitals were public hospitals disposing of about 70% of all beds. From the hospitals funded by the federal health funds 123 out of 136 hospitals were public i.e. about 90%. Figure 4.3 Hospitals in Austria (ownership status) Carriers 7,79 Private entities % of total number of beds 19,32 17,25 15,91 Religious orders/-communities % of total number of hospitals 11,11 9,85 Local government, municipalities 51,61 Federal States 32,20 1,59 3,79 Associations/ Foundations 8,04 Accident- and Pension insurance 12,50 Health insurance funds and health care institutions (Fürsorgeverbände) Federation 1,69 2,65 0,93 3,79 0,00 % of total hospitals / beds 10,00 20,00 30,00 40,00 50,00 60,00 Source: Yearly average population: Number of hospitals, number of beds: BMGF, received 21/09/2006, own calculations The federal states or rather the regional associations are the legal representatives for 32% of the hospitals with 52% of the beds. 10% of hospitals with 11% of the beds are sponsored by the local government. Sickness funds, welfare associations, accident and pension insurance funds operate 15% of the hospitals with 10% of the beds. Religious orders and denominations are legally responsible for 16% of the hospitals with 17% of the beds. 23% of the hospitals with 9% of the beds are assigned in legal terms to private individuals, private associations, societies or foundations. Sponsorship of the remaining hospitals (4% with around 1% of the beds) rests with the Federation (army hospitals, hospitals of reformatory establishments). Over the past years the proprietary structures of hospitals have undergone significant change, namely successive privatization of the management of public hospitals in the form of hospital operations management agencies. This development has occurred in all federal states. Hospital operations management agencies are responsible for the administration of about 50% of all hospital beds.336 The function of these agencies is to fulfill the care requirements & orders set out by the federal states and, on behalf of the federal states, put into effect strategic decisions.337 336 Hofmarcher et al. (2001). ″Focus: The Austrian Hospital Sector – One System or Nine?″ Health System Watch I in Fidler, A.H., Haslinger, R.R., Hofmarcher, M.M., Jesse, M., Palu, T. (2005). ″Incorporation of public hospitals: a “silver bullet” against overcapacity, managerial bottlenecks and resource constraints? Case studies from Austria and Estonia.″ p.5, accessed at http://vega.medinfo.hu/civiltajekoztatas/kepek/ho/anyagok/incorporation.doc on 09/01/2006 337 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 116 Tertiary care Tertiary care (long term out-patient and in-patient care) comprises the areas of medical measures for rehabilitation, psychiatry, and nursing. Psychiatric care takes place both in in-patient and out-patient form (hospitals, specialists for psychiatry, psychologists, etc). The assurance of care with extramural services rests with the federal states. In the field of rehabilitation social insurance funds in Austria run 30 specialist hospitals.338 Moreover there are 19 contract partner establishments.339 Beyond this there are 12 convalescent homes and sanatoria and 5 recuperation homes.340 In the year 2000 about half of the old peoples homes and nursing homes in Austria belonged to the public sector (federal states, local authorities, social services associations), about 27% belonged to the non-profit making sector (private facilities which offer their services on a -profit making basis) and about 22% to the profit oriented sector (private, profit-oriented institutions).341 Social services are offered by private and mostly non-profit organizations. The role of government in relation to providers The federation uses planning instruments for Health care planning. The most important planning instrument is the Austrian Structural Plan for Health (Österreichischer Strukturplan Gesundheit, ÖSG), formerly the Austrian Hospital and Major Equipment Plan (Österreichischer Krankenanstalten- und Großgeräteplan, ÖKAP or ÖGGP) passed on the 16th December by the Federal Health Commission in accordance with article 4 of the 15a B-VG agreement. The plan presents a mandatory Austria-wide basis for the integrated planning of the care structure in the Austrian health system and covers the areas of in-patient and outpatient care as well as rehabilitation and nursing interfaces. The planning for services offered is set out up to a planning horizon of 2010. Therein Austria is split into four overall care zones which are, in turn, divided up into a further 32 care regions. The federal states have developed detailed plans based on the ÖSG, which sets out the basic conditions. The last agreed status of the ÖKAP/ÖGGP was evaluated up to mid 2005 and remained effective until the end of 2005. Important for social insurance is that for the first time the Hauptverband was given a formal right to participate in the development of planning guidelines. The provision of services is linked with the fulfillment of quality criteria (incl. minimum number of consultations and accessibility) whereby the majority of the quality criteria pertaining to structure still comply with those in the ÖKAP of 2003. Also part of the new ÖSG is capacity planning at a regional level for hospitals financed by the agencies for health care in the federal states and an up to date plan for large scale medical equipment. The ÖSG is constantly being revised and developed further. The aim is an integrated care plan. That means that areas of health care beyond those of acute hospitals are to be included in planning, e.g. medical care for out-patients, additional in-patient and out-patient rehabilitation. The ÖSG 2006 provides basic planning directives at federal state level. It is then the duty of the federal states, hospital agencies, and social 338 Mag. Romana Ruda (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). Interview 31 March 2006 339 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger Eds. (2006). Handbook for Medical Rehabilitation. Edition 2005/2006 340 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB (2006). Handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2005, Vienna. 341 Nam, H. (2003). ″Nursing homes and homes for long-term care in Austria: ownership structure, supply structure and employment, first results from the project „Employment in the Austrian Non-Profit Sector“.″ Vienna University of Economics and Business Administration, Department for Social Policy. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 117 insurance funds to undertake the detailed planning. This development allows the individual players greater room for maneuver whereupon it is hoped that integrated planning will result.342 As has been the practice up to now, sanction measures will come into operation in cases of a deviation from the terms of the Austrian Structural Plan (see articles 35 and 36 of the agreement). For implementation of the health plan the federation uses the services of the Austrian Institute for Health Care (Österreichisches Bundesinstitut für Gesundheitswesen, ÖBIG). In the course of the health reform 2005 funds were made available for a cooperative body (Reformpool) which facilitates the definition of mutual structural changes or projects, which result in the shifting of services between intramural and extramural care. A precondition hereto is prior settlement or rather a precise agreement between the Federation-concerned social insurance with regards to the particular measures. Collective trials for the development of new cooperative models were developed as well as mechanisms to ensure the funding of the health system. In 2005 and 2006 the reform pool will be allocated a minimum of 1%, and in 2007 and 2008 a minimum of 2%, of the total intra and extramural funds.343 The Federal Health Agency (Bundesgesundheitsagentur) (replaces the Structural Fund (Strukturfonds, in existence up to 2005) has numerous duties in the fields of planning, regulation, and financing (see Article 15a B-VG Agreement, article 11), including the formulation of quality specifications for provision of services, planning of services, definition of scope for interface management between sectors or the formulation of guidelines for the Reformpool.344 Beyond this, within the framework of the health reform 2005, the federation issued new terms for quality assurance (Quality of Health Law (Gesundheitsqualitätsgesetz)) as well as for the handling of data (Health Data Transmission Law (Gesundheitstelematikgesetz)), which could lead to significant changes in service provision. The provision of high quality care as well as the initiation of systematic and comprehensive highquality work has top priority in Austria. In the field of health data transmission there are directives on ehealth, the electronic health act (ELGA) and electronic prescriptions (e-prescription). Due to numerous legal directives, the federation additionally exerts influence on the activities of service providers. Amongst others, this includes the areas of education, hygiene (sanitary control), data protection, documentation, quality assurance. These may partly be found in the occupational laws of the health professions, partly in individual laws e.g. medical product law, pharmaceutical law, etc. Licensing of (public and/or private) health care facilities Construction and operation of hospitals requires authorization from the appropriate Federation. Legal basis is the Hospital Law, 3§§ 3ff. In this paragraph requirements for gaining authorization are set out, amongst others, formal criteria must be met (applications must describe in detail the intended purpose of the establishment and services offered, proprietorship or right of user of the facilities must be proven, certain building, fire, and health policy regulations must be adhered to). Furthermore the need must be demonstrated with due consideration given to existing care structures, and there must be no concerns with regards the operator. For establishments financed by funds (from the federal health agencies) or those operated by health insurance funds additional special regulations apply (e.g. § 339 ASVG). During the course of the authorization procedure an assessment certificate must be obtained from the State Governor, which addresses sanitary control. Sanitary control is transferred to the district administration authorities by means of indirect federal administration and managed by public health officers. Issue of authorization is further bound to the existence of the required equipment (both medical and technical), the fulfilment of health and safety regulations as well as compliance with provincial legal planning agreements. Conformance to quality criteria in terms of structure must also be proven. 342 Ministry of Health and Women, www.bmgf.gv.at, accessed on 08/05/2006 In 2002 this was around 14.4 Bill. Euro (Federal Ministry of Health and Women, BMGF) 344 Health Reform Law 2005, § 59a, para.1 343 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 118 The Federation must be notified of any planned changes to the premises or any other significant changes (e.g. services provided). In order to set up a practice a doctor must be eligible to carry out his profession independently and be registered at the Austrian Medical Chamber. Should he be employed elsewhere and wish to continue in this job, approval of the legal representative of the establishment is required. Upon notification of the Medical Chamber a second practice may be opened at any time.345 The doctor must also notify the Medical Chamber when the practice opens. An official sanitary inspection is not carried out at this time however the doctor remains subject to supervision by the sanitary authorities. In accordance with § 56 of the Doctors Law the doctor is obliged to maintain his practice in compliance with the hygienic requirements. A practice inspection may be carried out by the public health officer of the district authorities whenever deemed necessary. In doing so a representative of the Medical Chamber is called upon. In the case of deficiencies the doctor is given a time period within which to rectify these. In the case of serious deficiencies, which may threaten the lives and health of patients, the practice may be closed until such a time as the problems have been resolved.346 The number and distribution of contract doctors with social health insurance are regulated in Austria by a Location Plan (Stellenplan) which is negotiated between the Hauptverband, the regional sickness fund and the respective regional Medical Chamber. The general contract regulates, amongst other things, stipulation of the number and regional distribution of contract doctors, the choice of these as well as the rights and obligations of contract doctors. Details regarding the practice site, practice opening hours and possible special agreements are given in the individual contracts with doctors. Allocation of available posts takes place according to so called priority criteria (incl. proof of professional competence, certain structural requirements347). Only a few health insurance funds (e.g. the regional sickness fund of Vorarlberg) carry out an inspection of the practice prior to contract completion.348 Some health insurance funds couple the award of a contract with the existence of barrier free access in accordance with ÖNORM B 1600. The contract doctor is obliged to fulfil all legal requirements (hygiene, security, documentation, data protection, etc.) and undergo inspection when deemed necessary. All authorised establishments/facilities such as hospitals, convalescent homes, care facilities, sanatoriums, etc. are supervised by the sanitary authorities. The district authority decides how often and to what extent sanitary inspections take place.349 Licensing of doctors, dentists, nurses and allied practitioners Licensing of doctors rests with the Austrian Medical Chamber (delegated by the Federal Minister of Health and Women) and is followed by registration in the Directory of Doctors, which lists all licensed doctors authorised to practice in Austria and is publicly available. The legal basis is the Doctors Law (§ 27). The directory contains information with respect to name, job title, other academic titles, diplomas awarded by the Austrian Medical Chamber and regional Medical Chambers, contracts with Social insurance funds, or health care facilities as well as place of work, practice address, service address or home address. 345 Medical Chamber of Lower Austria, planning the private practice, accessed under: http://www.arztnoe.at/localfiles/4286_.pdf, on 09/06/2006 346 Doctors Law (Ärztegesetz) 1998 (BGBl. Nr. I 169/1998) 347 Promise by the applicant to make a serious effort to provide disabled access in accordance with the ÖNORM B1600 „Barrier free building“ as well as ÖNORM B 1601 „Special building requirements for disabled and elderly people“ from commencement of the contract. 348 Dr. Gregoritsch (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). 9 May 2006 (telephone) 349 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 119 Personal I.D. and/or educational certification must be presented in order to practice medicine, whether freelance or as an employee. Furthermore, proof of nationality, suitability in terms of health, as well as, a copy of any criminal records, are also necessary. Entry in the Directory of Doctors is confirmed by the issue of a photo identity card (doctors I.D.). Medical practice may only be commenced upon receipt of confirmation. The appropriate district authorities are notified of new entries by the Austrian Medical Chamber. Special conditions apply for the accreditation of qualifications gained abroad. An evaluation of comparability with Austrian qualifications is carried out by the Austrian Medical Chamber. The licensing procedure or any requirements for re-certification in other non-medical health professions are not explained further within the scope of this report, for these the relevant professional laws or education and training regulations should be referred to. Periodic re-licensing of facilities/practitioners Revalidation via an examination is not required in Austria. However the doctor must fulfil certain requirements regarding continuing professional training. Within the framework of the voluntary Diploma program for continuing medical education (Diplomfortbildungsprogramm, DFP) run by the Austrian Medical Chamber (150 hours in three years) a “non-verification” is not threatened with loss of licence. In the areas of doctors with their own practice there are partial quality evaluations. It is not expected that revalidation will be introduced in the near future.350 Licensing of medical equipment and drugs New products must be approved by the European Agency for the Evaluation of Medical Products, EMEA (Europäische Agentur für die Beurteilung von Arzneimitteln) for all other medication reciprocal approval of nationally licensed pharmaceuticals within the EU is planned. It is intended that this measure will speed up the licensing procedure. From the beginning of 2006 the Austrian Agency for Health and Nutritional Safety (Österreichische Agentur für Gesundheit und Ernährungssicherheit, AGES)351, founded in 2002, will progressively be assigned new duties. This will occur under the heading “PharmMed-Austria” and to support the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. These duties include all tasks related to licensing of pharmaceuticals as well as testing pharmaceuticals and medical products. High-level or sovereign duties rest with the Federal Office for Safety in the Health System (Bundesamt für Sicherheit im Gesundheitswesen) a subordinate department of the Ministry of Health and Women. Prior to 2006 the “Section III Health Care” within the Ministry of Health and Women, with the support of the Federal Institute for Pharmaceuticals, was responsible for licensing of drugs.352 “The AGES PharmMed fulfils the operational duties of the Federal Administration with respect to pharmaceuticals and medical products in accordance with legislative order, as set out in the Pharmaceutical Law (Arzneimittelgesetz, AMG), the Medical Products Law (Medizinproduktegesetz, MPG), Law for the Introduction of Medicines (Arzneiwareneinfuhrgesetz, AWEG), Blood Safety Law (Blutsicherheitsgesetz, BSG) as well as in the ordinances of these”.353 350 Mag. Holler (Austrian Medical Chamber). Interview 12 January 2006 Dr. Holzgruber (Medical Chamber of Vienna). 31 March 2006 (via email) Rowe, A., García-Barbero, M. (2005). ″Regulation and licensing of physicians in the WHO European Region.″ WHO Report, p. 42 351 The Austrian Agency for Health and Nutritional Safety carries out a wide range of duties in the field of nutritional safety for the Republic of Austria (www.ages.at) 352 Austrian Agency for Health and Nutritional Safety, accessed at www.ages.at on 08/05/2006 353 The Austrian Agency for Health and Nutritional Safety (AGES), accessed at http://www13.ages.at/servlet/sls/Tornado/web/ages/content/397CCFF0057354E5C125715D003720A4 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 120 Both the licensing of pharmaceuticals and the regulation of pharmacies and wholesale remain matters for the Federation. Negotiations regarding reimbursements for pharmaceuticals are the responsibility of the social insurance funds. In Austria the most important legal foundations in these areas are the Pharmaceutical Law (Arzneimittelgesetz) (licensing of pharmaceuticals) and the Medical Products Law (Medizinproduktegesetz) (medical equipment), plus numerous EU regulations. Certification of safety (radiation, fire, environmental and occupational hazards) Organizations are subject to certain legal obligations, amongst other things, they must determine risks within the organization and evaluate these, as well as, define measures for their elimination. In many areas E-norms (E-standards), ÖNORMEN, or other norms or standards are applicable and must be adhered to. The legal bases in the field of safety at work are the Employee Protection Law (Arbeitnehmerschutzgesetz), the general Employee Protection Regulations (Arbeitnehmerschutzverordnung), the Workplace Regulations (Arbeitsstättenverordnung), the Electrical Protection Regulations (Elektroschutzverordnung), the regulations on noise and vibrations, the fire regulations, safety regulations concerning electrical equipment or other dangers like gases, steam or radiation, noise protection regulations. In the Employee Protection Law (Arbeitnehmerschutzgesetz) provision is made for medical and safety supervision for all employees at work. This is independent of size of the organization. Here the accident insurance funds are responsible for the supervision of small businesses. This supervision is free of charge. The AUVA has set up prevention centres in its federal and satellite sites for this purpose.354 For larger businesses or small businesses which do not call upon these services, there is the possibility of employing a person for the job of prevention (occupational medical doctor, safety staff).355 The AUVA runs the safety-related test centre (Sicherheitstechnische Prüfstelle, STP), an accredited registered laboratory and control centre. The inspection scope ranges from tools and supplies for work (e.g. ladders), flammable and explosive properties (e.g. of dust) and workplace conditions (e.g. noise, vibrations, harmful substances, and magnetic fields).356 Furthermore, the workplace safety inspection is carried out by private institutions such as the TÜV Austria357, an accredited test centre for the inspection of machinery, machine parts, technical equipment and products. Other institutions358 dealing with safety in the health system include health insurance funds, some ministries, professional representative bodies, professional medical associations359, the Austrian Academy for Occupational Medicine (Österreichische Akademie für Arbeitsmedizin), the works inspection, the Austrian Institute of Standards (Österreichische Normungsinstitut) or rescue organizations. The Ministry of Health and Women has the following responsibilities in the field of radiation protection: • • Matters of radiation hygiene, medical radiation protection and medical radiology Medical evaluation of the implementation of ionised and non-ionised radiation as well as radiopharmaceuticals Legal foundations are the Radiation Protection Law (Strahlenschutzgesetz) (BGBl. 1969/227), the Radiation Protection Law – Alignment with the EU (Strahlenschutz-EU-Anpassungsgesetz) 2002 (BGBl. 146/2002) and 2004 (BGBl. 137/2004), the Radiation Protection Regulations (Strahlenschutzverordnung) (BGBl. 1972/47), the Patient Protection Guidelines (Richtlinie Patientenschutz) 97/43/Euratom, Guidelines to the Radiation Protection basic standards (Richtlinie Strahlenschutzgrundnormen) 96/29/Euratom, as well as, the decree on the immediate applicability of guidelines in the area of radiation protection in the medical field 354 Austrian Social Insurance for Occupational Risks, www.auva.at, accessed on 09/05/2006 AUVA, Safety-related and occupational medicine cost-free support service, AUVAsicher, issue 2005/2006, accessed at http://www.auva.at/mediaDB/102426.PDF on 09/05/2006 356 Austrian Social Insurance for Occupational Risks accessed at www. auva.at, on 09/05/2006 357 Technology Watchdog (Technischer Überwachungsverein) 358 Works inspection (Arbeitsinspektion), accessed at http://www.arbeitsinspektion.gv.at/AI/default.htm on09/05/2006 359 Fachgesellschaft 355 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 121 from 13th May 2000. In addition there are the Medical Radiation Protection Regulations (Medizinische Strahlenschutzverordnung) 2004 (BGBl. II 409/2004), as well as, diverse ÖNORMEN on radiation protection. Information on this topic is also available from, amongst others, the Austrian Association for Radiation Protection (Österreichischer Verband für Strahlenschutz).360 Voluntary external quality assessment and improvement programs In Austria quality certification or accreditation are not yet standard, but are something special. Quality oriented thinking is becoming increasingly more significant in the health system and with it the trend of implementation of diverse quality models. In Austria, amongst others, the following models/instruments for quality control and quality improvement are being implemented.361 Certification362: * ISO –9000 ff. Certification of health related institutions Accreditation: * EFQM - accreditation * Accreditation in accordance with the Joint Commission (since 1999 also offered in form of international accreditation) Others: * Quality indicator project363 * Peer review/ Visitation * Quality circles of the Medical Chamber * Quality group of the AUVA for medics in the workplace by AUVAsicher Further initiatives in quality assurance or quality control (exemplary): * Quality report compilation (Qualitätsberichterstattung, QBE) of the federation (BMGF)364 * Uniqa Gut Drauf Preis365 * Approval for activities/events, accreditation of activities/events within the framework further vocational training programs of the Medical Chamber366 * Quality measures or projects: of the social insurance funds367, the Ministry, others In an article, published in November 2004, in the journal Clinicum, it was noted that certification in accordance with ISO 9001 is the most widely used method in Austria. The International Standards Organization (ISO) is a voluntary amalgamation of standards institutes of 156 countries.368 The aim is to develop uniform standards/norms. Through this method the organization can attain a seal of approval for its quality management system. Although this standard stems from industry it is nevertheless often adopted in 360 Austrian Association for Radiation Protection (Österreichischer Verband für Strahlenschutz), accessed at http://www.strahlenschutzverband.at/ 361 Poznanski, U. (2004). ″quality for sure (Qualität mit Brief und Siegel), Clinicum 11:2004, accessed at http://www.medical-tribune.at/dynasite.cfm?dssid=4171&dsmid=59942&dspaid=417186 on09/05/2006 Czypionka, T., Riedel, M., Röhrling, G. (2006). ″Europe in motion: Quality of care in physicians’ practices.″ in Health System Watch I-2006, supplement to the Austrian journal of Social insurance Soziale Sicherheit 362 Third party confirmation, that a facility is maintaining certain standards, taken from Czypionka, T., Riedel, M., Röhrling, G. (2006), ″Europe in motion: Quality of care in physicians’ practices.″ in Health System Watch I-2006, supplement to the Austrian journal of Social insurance Soziale Sicherheit 363 Project description of the QIP (Quality indicator project) project 364 Quality reporting: www.qbe.at 365 Dr. Geyer (Federal Ministry of Health and Women). questionnaire 29 December 2005, associated website: http://www.give.or.at/gesundheitspreis/gdp_2002.htm 366 Academy of Doctors, program of continuous medical education (Diplomfortbildungsprogramm, DFP): http://www.arztakademie.at/fileadmin/template/main/med02PDFs/03_2002DFPAkk.pdf 367 e.g. contract partner control, hospital audits by social insurance (Spitalseinschau) 368 International Organization for Standardization, accessed at www.iso.org, on 09/05/2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 122 other areas, amongst others, the health system (mostly in parts of the organization). Some departments are more suited to ISO certification than others, e.g. technical/scientific laboratories. An inspection takes place once a year, a so called audit. In Austria in 1999 a total of 3400 ISO certificates were awarded and only 18 denied. Accreditation in accordance with the Joint Commission369 was developed in the USA, in contrast to the ISO method, especially for the health system. In the course of accreditation not only individual departments, but the hospital as a whole, is part of the quality assessment process. Central pillars of the system are patient expectations, patient rights, and patient safety. The accreditation is valid for three years. In November 2004 two Austrian hospitals were accredited (LKH Villach, NTK Kapfenberg). The EFQM (European Foundation for Quality Management) Model orients itself in line with the TQM (Total Quality Management) approach and covers all parts and functions of a business with respect to both structure and process. It is based on a self assessment approach whereby an organization can aim for a maximum target of 500 points. External assessment is made possible through participation in a Quality Award. The model is suitable as a basis for benchmarking with other organizations. In Austria there is the AFQM (Austrian Foundation for Quality Management). At the peer review or independent assessment the divisions of other colleagues are visited. These carry out external, neutral quality control, based on specific indicators. At the time of publication this model was not very common however in the meantime it has gained more prominence, both in hospitals and out-patient facilities. The international Quality Indicator Project (QIP) was developed in 1986 in Maryland (USA) as a model for continual quality improvement in hospitals. Worldwide more than 1900 hospitals are taking part in this project, 140 of these outside the USA and of these more than 30 Austrian hospitals (above all in the region of Upper Austria). The aim of this project is the measurement and evaluation of the care processes as well as benchmarking against other institutions based on various indicators. The system pursues quality improvement by means of self assessment, whereby hospitals receive continual feedback about their own and anonymous reference values. The methodology is uniform worldwide and covers medical indicators as well as measurement of organizations and coordination processes. Data are collected quarter yearly similarly feedback is given at these time intervals.370 “Quality groups are working groups of 6-12 doctors, who adhere to the basic principles of voluntary, continual, topic-based, experience-based, and target-based work. Their work includes the analysis of day to day medical practice, collegial comparison and exchange of experiences of the “lone fighters”, raising awareness of agreement and disparity in the various areas of work”. In March 2003 there were 175 active quality groups across Austria, with almost half of these in Styria.371 369 Joint Commission on Accreditation of Healthcare Organizations (JCAHO) International Quality Indicator Project (QIP), accessed under http://www.forumq.at/Downloads/QiP.pdf, on 09/05/2006 371 Austrian Medical Chamber, accessed under http://www.aerztekammer.at/?type=module&aid=convert&url=%2Fsrv%2Fdav%2Foak%2Fakwebsite%2FIQS%2FIQSQZ.htm, on 09/05/2006 370 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 123 5. ALLOCATIVE EFFICIENCY AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION Allocative efficiency can be defined as an economy that provides its members with the amounts and types of goods and services that they most prefer. Improvement in allocative efficiency can be achieved by reorienting care from hospital to outpatient, primary and social care, for example. Typically there are three ways to examine allocative efficiency: allocation between health care and other sectors of the economy; how money is allocated to different sectors within the health care system, such as between acute care and preventive services; and how resources are allocated to specific clinical services, such as which drugs to reimburse and how much.372 Allocative efficiency is difficult to measure because data are limited and there are methodological problems. One indication of the allocative efficiency of the health system is the level of expenditure by sector. However, the analysis depends largely on judgments about the relative value and effectiveness of different sectors. It is important to highlight that determining the extent to which this allocation improves population health relies on detailed data on outcomes, which are not forthcoming. Data from the OECD have suggested that the relative size of the ambulatory and acute sectors varies between countries but does not systematically differ according to the predominant source of funding. In most health systems in recent decades, the pharmaceutical sector has grown faster than any other sector. However, aggregate data do not clearly show whether the growth in pharmaceuticals has substituted for other expenditure. For example, did the increase in drug expenditure reduce admissions and lengths of stay in inpatient settings or did it just reflect waste and increased profit for drug companies? While Table 5.1 outlines the distribution of health spending across the different health sectors in a selection of European countries, data are incomplete and in some cases unreliable. Therefore it is very difficult to draw conclusions about allocative efficiency based on aggregate data from one year. However one can see that spending on inpatient care in some countries remains quite high despite the trend of deinstitutionalization and increasing use of day care as opposed to more expensive inpatient care; the range of spending on inpatient care is from 26% of total health spending in Spain to 42% in Austria. Also, spending on pharmaceuticals is higher than on physician care in many countries, and constitute over 20% of total health spending in Slovak Republic, Poland, Spain, Czech Republic, Hungary, and Italy. Whereas, spending on public health and prevention is surprisingly low, less than 2% in most countries. Table 5.1 Spending on health in different sectors (as a proportion of total health spending) in selected European countries, latest available year Inpatient Physicians Dentists Pharmaceuticals Public care health Austria 41.7 15.7 6.6 13 2 Czech Republic 36 22.9 5.4 22 2 Denmark 30.1 18.7 4.5 9.4 0.5 Finland 34.8 28.6 5.8 16.3 3.9 France 33.8 11.7 4.9 18.9 2.9 Germany 34.7 10.1 7.6 14.6 4.7 Hungary 29 4 8.4 27.6 Italy 42.4 21.4 0.6 Luxembourg 33.1 18.3 3.8 8.5 1.2 Netherlands 37.6 4.9 Poland 28.1 14.7 5.4 29.6 1.7 Slovak Republic 30.4 38.5 1.6 Spain 25.9 26.1 5.1 22.8 1.4 Sweden 31.3 6.6 12.3 372 Mossialos and Dixon, eds., Funding Health Care: Options for Europe. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 124 Source: OECD Health data 2006 Pooling and resource allocation are important instruments in achieving appropriate risk protection, equity and allocative efficiency. Strategic resource allocation refers to the challenge of distributing national-level health care funds to health care plans or ‘purchasers’ in order to maximise efficiency and equity.373 Four main types of health care financing systems can be identified: competitive insurance plans or sickness funds (Belgium, Germany, the Netherlands); employer-based insurance plans (Austria, France, Greece); local governments (Denmark, Finland, Italy, Norway, Sweden); and centralised government (Ireland, Portugal, Spain, UK). Methods of funding the health plans in Europe have been gradually moving away from full retrospective reimbursement towards reimbursing using a fixed schedule of fees (e.g. diagnostic-related groups; DRGs) and using fixed budgets to fund prospectively in order to increase efficiency and curb expenditure growth. Within the fixed-budget resource allocation mechanism, there are four methods of distributing funds based on the size of the plan’s bid, political negotiation, historical precedent, or an independent measure of health care needs. The last method, which takes a more scientific approach, has become increasingly common, especially in the form of capitation payments. Capitation with risk adjustment is preferred to others methods mainly due to equity and efficiency considerations. Because people’s health needs vary depending on personal and social characteristics, risk adjustment is needed in order to enable the cost of each member to reflect their relative health care expenditure needs. Recent efforts have been made to increase equity in resource allocation. The resource allocation formula used in England was adapted in 1995 to take into account inequalities in health (see below). Also, a new formula for allocation was introduced in 1992 in the Stockholm area in Sweden, in order to target populations with poorer health and certain socio-economic characteristics.374 Competition between sickness funds was introduced in the Netherlands in 1988 and in Germany in 1996, which led to sickness funds employing risk adjustment mechanisms. The Dutch risk adjustment scheme adjusts for age, sex, region, employment and disability status; the German scheme accounts for income and average expenditure by age and sex.375 Despite this increasingly scientific approach to resource allocation, there remains considerable scope for altering the budgetary schemes, both prospectively and retrospectively. For instance, retrospective negotiations with the central payer occurs in Italy and Spain, premiums or local taxes paid by plan members may be altered, as in Scandinavia, and delaying or rationing health care occurs in Norway, Sweden and the UK. Also, while resource allocation in Portugal is based somewhat on capitation, this method only accounted for about 8% of the total budget in 1998, with the remainder determined through incremental budgeting based on past levels of spending. It appears that attempts to determine budgets through objective assessments of needs may be impeded by historical and political pressures. According to a survey of resource allocation schemes in Europe, most countries use a capitation system with risk adjustment, however variations exist. Only Austria, Greece and Ireland have no element of capitation. Instead, Austria and Greece have employment-based insurance, which are self-financing in Austria and partly subsidized in Greece through political negotiation and historical precedent, and Irish reimbursement is based on activity such as DRGs.376 373 N Rice and P Smith, "Strategic Resource Allocation and Funding Decisions," in Funding Health Care: Options for Europe, ed. E. Mossialos, et al. (Buckingham: Open University Press, 2002). 374 F Diderichsen, E. Varde, and M Whitehead, "Resource Allocation to Health Authorities: The Quest for an Equitable Formula in Britain and Sweden," British Medical Journal 315 (1997). 375 R Busse, "Risk Structure Compensation in Germany's Statutory Health Insurance," European Journal of Public Health 11, no. 2 (2001), K Okma and J.D. Poelert, "Implementing Prospective Budgeting for Dutch Sickness Funds," European Journal of Public Health 11 (2001). 376 Rice and Smith, "Strategic Resource Allocation and Funding Decisions." LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 125 Where capitation methods are used, there are associated risk-adjustment mechanisms based on patterns of health care utilization, with the exception of Spain, Norway, Portugal, and Scotland. The needs factors that are included in the risk adjustment formulas include demography, employment and disability status (e.g. in the Netherlands and Northern Ireland), geographical location, morbidity, (e.g. in Portugal, Belgium, Finland and the Netherlands), mortality (e.g. in Belgium, Italy, Northern Ireland, Norway, Scotland and Wales), and social factors such as unemployment (Belgium, the Netherlands and Stockholm county), marital status (Norway and Stockholm county), family structure (France and Norway), housing quality (Belgium) and income (Finland). England has a well developed system of risk adjustment for the allocations to purchasers – primary care trusts. This method of resource allocation has been in place since 1977, following recommendations from the Resource Allocation Working Party (RAWP) to address geographical inequities in hospital supply and better match resources with local needs. The factors used to ‘weight’ the payments have become more extensive over time. At first only age structure, local input costs and standardized mortality rates were used to adjust allocations, however later risk-adjustment mechanisms included morbidity, unemployment rates, elderly people living at home, ethnic origin and socio-economic status. The current weighted capitation formula consists of four components: hospital and community health services, prescribing, primary medical services, and HIV/AIDS (which became part of revenue allocations from 2002/03).377 These are combined using national expenditure weights, which based on 2005/6 expenditures are: hospital and community health weighting representing 77.4%; prescribing 13.2%, primary medical services 8.8% and HIV/AIDS 0.6%. 5.1 Health technology assessment Health technology plays an integral role in the EU health care system. During the past half-century, all member states have increased their technological base for health care, both in terms of knowledge and investments in equipment, devices, and pharmaceuticals. Although many innovations carry the potential to bring significant value to patients in comparison with existing practice, the adoption and financing of such technologies, especially those entailing significant investment costs, can prove problematic in resourceconstrained health care environments. In fact, the continual introduction of new medical products has been accompanied by a steady increase in health care costs in many countries378. The burgeoning growth in health technologies increases the need to ascertain the value of new innovations and validate their appropriate position in the spectrum of care. While countries employ a wide array of approaches to control the costs of health technology and support the optimal use of such products, health technology assessment (HTA) has assumed an increasing role in national priority-setting and health policy processes. The general objective of HTA is to ascertain the effects of technology on health, resource use, and other aspects of the health system (e.g., health care budgets, national economy). Moreover, HTA is also concerned with the societal, organization, legal, and ethical consequences of implementing health technologies or interventions into the health system. From a policy context, HTA provides a range of stakeholders with accessible, useable, and evidence-based information, typically in the form of assessment reports, to support various decisions surrounding a given health technology or intervention. In almost all countries of the EU, programs for HTA have been established either through the provision of new agencies or institutes, or in established academic units or governmental and non-governmental entities (Table 5.2). 377 http://www.dh.gov.uk/assetRoot/04/11/20/67/04112067.pdf Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, "OECD Heath Data: A Comparative Analysis of 30 OECD Countries," (Paris: OECD, 2002). 378 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 126 Table 5.2 Institutions and advisory bodies responsible for HTA activities in the EU Federation of Austrian Social Insurance Institution/Drug Evaluation Austria Committee Ludwig Boltzmann Institute Health Technology Assessment National Institute for Sickness and Invalidity Insurance Belgium Denmark Reimbursement Committee Finland Pharmaceuticals Pricing Board France Economic Committee for the Health Products/Transparency Commission Germany Federal Joint Committee/Institute for Quality and Efficiency in Health Care Italy Pricing and Reimbursement Committee of the Medicines Agency Netherlands National Health Insurance Board/Committee for Pharmaceutical Aid Norway Pharmaceuticals Pricing Board Spain Spanish Agency for Health Technology Assessment Sweden LFN Pharmaceutical Benefits Board Switzerland Swiss Federal Office of Public Health/Confederal Drug Commission United Kingdom National Institute of Clinical Excellence/National Coordinating Centre for Health Technology Assessment/Scottish Medicines Consortium Most review bodies can be categorized as serving either an advisory or regulatory role in the decisionmaking process, depending on the intent and type of assessment required.379 For example, some countries, such as the Netherlands and Denmark, require the use of economic evaluations in reimbursement decisionmaking, while others (e.g., France) employ the assessments primarily to inform budgetary planning or guide clinical practice.380 The heterogeneity of HTA bodies in the EU reflects the differentiated environments of European health care and political systems, with variances in mandates, funding mechanisms, and roles in policy formulation. The use of HTA in heath care priority-setting entails both opportunities and challenges. Overall, HTA programs have generally enhanced transparency in decision-making processes through mechanisms such as independent systematic reviews, stakeholder involvement, and the production of guidance. However, different aspects of the HTA process introduce potential barriers to the effective use of economic evaluations. Specifically, issues have been raised on the following characteristics: 1) responsibility and membership of HTA entities, 2) assessment procedures and methods, and 3) the role in decision-making. Responsibility and membership of HTA entities The mandates or responsibilities of the assessment bodies vary by their general mission and overall policy objectives381. As one component in the broader health care decision-making process, HTA programs typically reflect the current policy landscape, such as the need to contain costs or improve access to a given area of intervention or service. Consequently, economic evaluations often coincide with policies regarding the pricing and utilization of medial technologies.382 379 A. Zentner, M. Valasco-Garrido, and R. Busse, "Methods for the Comparative Evaluation of Pharmaceuticals," GMS Health Technology Assessessment 1, no. Doc09 (2005). 380 J. Hutton et al., "Framework for Describing and Classifying Decision-Making Systems Using Technology Assessment to Determine the Reimbursement of Health Technologies (Fourth Hurdle Systems)," International Journal of Technology Assessment in Health Care 21, no. 1 (2006). 381 A. Anell, "Priority Setting for Pharmaceuticals," European Journal of Health Economics 5 (2004). 382 Hutton et al., "Framework for Describing and Classifying Decision-Making Systems Using Technology Assessment to Determine the Reimbursement of Health Technologies (Fourth Hurdle Systems)." LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 127 In many countries, the appraisal process is overseen by the health ministry, although separate institutions (e.g., NICE) are often involved to manage various aspects of the assessment. In many social insurancefunded health systems, however, the process is driven predominately by insurance organizations. Differences also exist in the execution of the evaluation(s). Some HTA bodies, for example, conduct the actual assessment via in-house committees, while others coordinate independent reviews by external bodies, such as university research institutions.383 The use of independent reviews presents both benefits and drawbacks to the assessment process. More specifically, independent reviews may lend greater transparency and help prevent or resolve potential disputes to resultant decisions. Conversely, they may introduce certain methodological challenges, such as use of particular study designs (i.e., RCTs) and potential disconnects between the economic model and systematic review. HTA entities also differ in their role in the decisionmaking process once the assessment is complete. For example, in some countries, the HTA body has the responsibility to develop guidance and recommend reimbursement status (e.g., UK), while in others, such decisions are primarily determined and promulgated by national authorities or insurance representatives (e.g., Finland). Moreover, some HTA committees are involved in negotiating product price and reimbursement with manufacturers. The composition of HTA entities and relevant processes involve a variety of stakeholders, including physicians, pharmacists, health economists, insurance and industry representatives, and patients. Anell found that most reimbursement status recommendations are determined first by scientific members (i.e., physicians, epidemiologists) with expertise in evaluation of medicines. Such decisions are further corroborated with academic entities, representatives from patient organizations, health economists, and in the case of NICE, managers within the NHS. The involvement of these groups differs across HTA bodies, although all agencies have some level of stakeholder involvement. It has been advocated that there be greater participation of patients and consumers, the ultimate end-users of a given technology, in the HTA process384. While stakeholder involvement is resource-intensive, it may lead to better assessments, reduce the number of appeals, and result in better implementations of HTA recommendations and guidance. Assessment procedures and methods HTA processes differ on a variety of issues regarding the actual assessment process, including topic selection; data requirements; and methodological approach(s) employed. Most HTA agencies struggle to keep pace with newly approved or introduced technologies. As a result, some type of prioritization process typically guides which medical products are evaluated. The topic agenda of some review bodies are set by national authorities or Departments of Health, while the Scottish Medicines Consortium (SMC), for instance, considers every new drug. As is it generally considered cost-ineffective to evaluate all existing technologies, review bodies incorporate various approaches to ensure the efficiency of the assessment process. For example, NICE allows groups of similar technologies to be compared, while certain procedures are required in the Netherlands to guide proper use of drugs that are not appraised. Although the range of topics covered by HTA agencies is quite broad, some areas, such as lower-technology and preventive technologies, tend to be understudied. Moreover, concerns have been raised regarding the transparency of the topic selection process. A perceived lack of transparency may exacerbate existing tensions between manufacturers and the stewards of health care budgets in terms of balancing access to technologies, product innovation, and health expenditures. HTA systems vary regarding the type and quality of evidence required for economic evaluations.385 Typically, manufacturers are required to submit a comprehensive summary of data on a product’s effectiveness and cost-effectiveness. Review entities differ, however, on the role of industry data in the assessment process. In Austria, Norway, and the Netherlands, for instance, HTA bodies review and validate all data provided by industry, which must be based on a systematic review of available clinical and 383 Anell, "Priority Setting for Pharmaceuticals." A. Coulter, "Perspectives on Health Technology Assessment: Response from the Patient's Perspective," International Journal of Health Technology Assessment 20, no. 1 (2004). 385 Hutton et al., "Framework for Describing and Classifying Decision-Making Systems Using Technology Assessment to Determine the Reimbursement of Health Technologies (Fourth Hurdle Systems)." 384 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 128 economic evidence.386 Other organizations (e.g., NICE) perform the systematic review in-house, independent of data provided by manufacturers. Some countries, such as France and Finland, do not require systematic reviews (although preferred), basing assessments primarily on a definite number of studies provided by industry.387 In addition to data requirements, countries employ different analytical frameworks and methods for the assessment and subsequent decision-making process.388 Most evaluations are guided by a variety of criteria including safety and clinical effectiveness, patient need and benefit, cost-effectiveness, budget impact, and cost of therapy.389 Some HTA bodies also frame the evaluation around equity considerations, product innovation, and public health impact. However, transparency of the criteria used in guiding the analytical framework is often lacking in most countries. A recent analysis by Anell found that some review entities rarely, if never, explicitly outline the relative weight and importance of the criteria used in the assessment. Moreover, while there are similarities across HTA bodies in terms of methodological approaches (e.g., use of randomized controlled trials, use of cost-utility analyses), assessments often differ on the following issues:390 • Sub-group analysis • Measures of quality of life impact • Costs included in the analysis • Discounting • Classification of product benefit (benefit vs. harm) • Modelling techniques • Choice of comparator • Use of sensitivity analysis • Approach to missing and incomplete data The choice of methods employed can significantly influence the result of the assessment and the comparability across studies and countries, which may ultimately impact the utility of HTA in the decisionmaking process.391 HTA role in decision-making The results of HTA are used, with varying levels of impact on decision-making, to plan capacities, to shape the benefit catalogue, or guide treatment provision. Almost all countries require assessments to ascertain reimbursement status, although differences exist regarding the importance of economic evidence in the decision process.392 France, for example, rarely considers such information when determining reimbursement status. Moreover, some reimbursement committees may only require assessments for patented drugs and new indications, or apply varying requirements to different types of products, such as generic drugs. HTA information is also used to restrict the use of products, especially innovative and expensive technologies. Specifically, reimbursement of such technologies can be conditioned to certain indications, patient populations, treatment settings, and therapeutic positioning (i.e., first- or second-line therapy).393 As aforementioned, HTAs play a role in the pricing of products and in negotiating special agreements (e.g., price-volume, cash rebates) with manufacturers.394 However, countries differ in terms of how closely the reimbursement and pricing process are linked. In particular, reimbursement decisions are 386 Zentner, Valasco-Garrido, and Busse, "Methods for the Comparative Evaluation of Pharmaceuticals." Ibid. 388 Hutton et al., "Framework for Describing and Classifying Decision-Making Systems Using Technology Assessment to Determine the Reimbursement of Health Technologies (Fourth Hurdle Systems)." 389 Anell, "Priority Setting for Pharmaceuticals.", Zentner, Valasco-Garrido, and Busse, "Methods for the Comparative Evaluation of Pharmaceuticals." 390 Zentner, Valasco-Garrido, and Busse, "Methods for the Comparative Evaluation of Pharmaceuticals." 391 S. Boulenger et al., "Can Economic Evaluations Be Made More Transferable?," European Journal of Health Economics 6 (2005). 392 Anell, "Priority Setting for Pharmaceuticals." 393 Zentner, Valasco-Garrido, and Busse, "Methods for the Comparative Evaluation of Pharmaceuticals." 394 Anell, "Priority Setting for Pharmaceuticals." 387 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 129 sometimes made prior to pricing, while in other cases, both the reimbursement and price of a product are considered simultaneously before a final decision is determined. The effectiveness of HTA in national priority-setting and health care policy-making depends on several considerations, including the quality of evidence used in the assessment, mechanisms for disseminating the decision, transparency of the evaluation, and processes for monitoring and reappraisal of the evidence.395 For example, a lack of trust in the methods used in the assessment or insufficient long-term outcome data can increase the complexity and uncertainty of the decision process or result in appeal procedures396. Moreover, broader system issues, such as decentralized management and ideologies on rationing care, may impede optimal implementation and use of economic evaluation.397 It is of import to ensure the optimal use of HTAs in decision-making processes, as requirements for economic assessments and their integration into benefit catalogues and practice guidelines potentially increases the costs for medicines, delays patient access to needed treatments, and stymies product innovation. To meet this end, a variety of measures should be considered across the aforementioned areas, including consistent application of HTA across countries; increased use of stakeholder groups; enhanced transparency regarding topic selection, methodologies, and criteria used in decision-making; strengthened international collaboration; and, greater alignment of manufacturer incentives to promote product innovation and the introduction of safe, effective, and affordable technologies into the marketplace. 5.1.1 HTA in Austria Over the past years Health Technology Assessment (HTA) has, with some delay in countries relying on social insurance, gained considerable prominence and is applied at both an academic level and in the decision making processes. HTA should be used to decide whether new services should be included/reimbursed or whether existing services should be re-assessed or excluded from reimbursement. A few years ago the status of the area of health technology assessment in Austria was described by experts as follows “With respect to the application of evaluations as a health political tool for the assessment of health services, Austria can be described as a developing country.”398 Systematic approaches were missing in this area. Some years ago a unit for Evidence Based Medicine was set up in the Hauptverband, which, on request, synthesised the existing and evaluated, basic scientific knowledge of particular topics. The Hauptverband was one of the pioneers encouraging development of knowledge and resources in the area of EBM. In the field of medication, efforts are being made to contain costs, which in part stem from health economic evaluations. In general instruments such as HTA, economic evaluation or EBM have more importance in the area of pharmaceuticals than for health services, for example when evaluating medical services. The latter area could take advantage of the knowledge and experience acquired in the field of pharmaceuticals. Over and above this there are a few expert groups, which carry out an assessment of the technology and offer their services.399 Evidence based medicine, HTA and health economic evaluations are only slowly gaining ground in Austria.400 Social insurance uses a dual system when considering whether new services should be included in the fee structure, whereby decisions are partially assisted by methodical evaluation. The question of reimbursement takes precedence after the conditions according to the legal definition of illness have been met. Although 395 Hutton et al., "Framework for Describing and Classifying Decision-Making Systems Using Technology Assessment to Determine the Reimbursement of Health Technologies (Fourth Hurdle Systems)." 396 J. Neumann, Using Cost-Effectiveness Analysis to Improve Heath Care: Opportunities and Barriers (New York: Oxford University Press, 2004). 397 F. Rutten, W. Brouwer, and L.. Niessen, "Practice Guidelines Based on Clinical and Economic Evidence," European Journal of Health Economics 6 (2005). 398 Wild, C., Gibis, B. (2003). ″Evaluations of health interventions in social insurance-based countries: Germany, the Netherlands, and Austria″, Health Policy 63, pp. 187-196. 399 Ludwig Boltzmann Institute for Health Technology Assessment (Dr. Claudia Wild) 400 Wild, C., Gibis, B. (2003). ″Evaluations of health interventions in social insurance-based countries: Germany, the Netherlands, and Austria″, Health Policy 63, pp. 187-196. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 130 economic analyses are carried out, this does not mean that decisions are inevitably based on the results of these analyses.401 5.2 Resource allocation in Austria Funding responsibilities in the Austrian Health care system are fragmented, especially in the area of hospital care, in which social insurance funds, the federal states, the Federation as well as the municipalities occupy an important role.402 In the estimate for the federal budget 2006, following the classification based on areas of expenditure, €834 million are planned for health care.403 Earmarked subsidies based on the Hospital Act account for €411 million.404 Federal states and municipalities are in charge of calculating their own health care expenditures. More than once political discussions took place questioning if the increase in health care expenditure should be aligned with the increase in GDP. Hofmarcher, Riedel and Röhrling (2004) calculated that, accumulated for the years 2004-2007, this would result in a funding gap of around €4.8 billion. In their model calculation the Health Econ researches come to the conclusion that a freezing of the health care budget would lead to negative distribution effects putting primarily private households at a disadvantage.405 Financial resources of social insurance are raised and used in a decentralized way. 81% of the funds are generated by contributions of the insured, 11% by contributions of the federation and 8% by other income. In the year 2005 social insurance accumulated a revenue of € 39,374 million. Financial means of social insurance are not related to the GDP or the federal budget.406 Funding of hospital care is partially organized by budgets. The Federation occupies primarily a steering function, the federal states are responsible for securing health care provision. Social insurance pays, in comparison to the Federation and the federal states, whose contributions are fixed amounts of money and fixed percentages of the revenue generated by VAT407, a lump sum payment for inpatient care according to § 447 para.1 ASVG. This covers all services of hospitals funded by the federal health care agencies in the field of inpatient care, semi-inpatient care, day-clinical care and care in outpatient departments, including services due to advances in medical technology.408 The lump sum reimburses about 42% of the total costs of fund-hospitals and is adjusted according to the increase in insurance contributions of the social insurance funds. In the year 2005 social insurance funds paid € 3.38 billion to the federal health care agencies.409 Furthermore social insurance pays a yearly prospective sum of €72.67 million to a fund (Privatkrankenanstalten-Finanzierungsfonds, PRIKRAF), set up in the Chamber of Commerce in 2002, for the hospitals not funded by the federal health agencies and for-profit hospitals i.e. sanatoria. Funding takes place by national performance related principles. 401 Dr. Endel, Dr. Schiller-Frühwirth (Main Organization of Austrian Social Insurance Funds, Hauptverband). Interview 18 November 2005 402 Fuentes, A., Wurzel, E., Wörgötter, A. (2006). ″Reforming federal fiscal relations in Austria.″ OECD Economics department Working paper No.474, pp. 1-34 403 Federal Ministry of Finance (2006). Budget 2006, Figures – Background – interrelationships, accessed at https://www.bmf.gv.at/Budget/Web_Zusammenhaenge_2006.pdf. on 20/06/2006 404 Federal Ministry of Finance (2006). Federal Finance Act 2006, Working guide – general overview, accessed at https://www.bmf.gv.at/Budget/Budget2006/Gesamtueberblick_2006_Web.pdf on 10/06/2006 405 Hofmarcher, M., Riedel, M., Röhrling, G. (2004). ″ Focus: Health remains precious to us – so what?″ Health System Watch I, supplement to the Austrian Journal of social insurance, Soziale Sicherheit, pp. 8-14 406 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2005). Handbook of social insurance in Austria 2004. Vienna 407 Tripold, M. (2005). The Austrian Health Care System 1945 up to the present in Sprenger, M. (Ed.) Public Health in Austria and Europe, , Pabst Science Publishers, Lengerich, 2005 408 Outpatient services provided in the course of the mother-child pass investigations and services explicitly excluded by mutual consent of social insurance and the relevant federal states are not reimbursed 409 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2006). Handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2006. Vienna LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 131 In the ambulatory setting social insurance has the obligation to provide health care services. Social insurance representatives negotiate contracts as well as fee schemes with the professional organizations or with the individual contract partners respectively. Funding of ambulatory care and of inpatient care is organised separately thus creating incentives for shifting of services between the different areas. 5.2.1 Decisions about the health care budget The legal basis for state budgeting is the Federal Constitution. Government is obliged to present a preliminary budget for the following year to parliament by latest ten weeks before the end of the year. The decision on the budget is to be taken before turn of the year.410 The Federal Health Care Agency replaces the former Structural Fund and is a fund governed by public law, an incorporated enterprise (mit eigener Rechtspersönlichkeit). The Federal Health Care Agency is responsible for setting up quality guidelines and for planning the supply of services for all sectors. Moreover the agency is committed to elaborate guidelines for budgeting for the hospital carriers and for social insurance and to develop performance-orientated remuneration systems.411 Furthermore it has, according to § 59a KAKuG, the duty of developing guidelines for the transparent presentation of the entire budgeting process and balance of accounts of the hospitals i.e. the hospital associations. In addition for social insurance for the ambulatory setting. The Federal Health Care Agency grants, based on § 57 KAKuG, the resources for the funding of public hospitals and distributes them to the agencies for health care of the federal states according to a defined formula (distribution key). The health care agencies in the federal states are responsible for planning, steering and funding of health care in the federal states. In the course of the above mentioned activities they are obliged to take into consideration the input of the Federal Health Care Agency. Use of financial resources of health insurance funds is, apart from inpatient care, handled autonomously by the individual sickness funds and is based on the obligation to provide services stated in the social insurance laws. 5.2.2 Allocation of budgets The amount of financial resources used for public health care is decided by the different funding institutions, namely social insurance funds, central government, the nine federal states, the municipalities and the legal representative e.g. religious orders. In the federal states the health care agencies have budgets for hospital care which are funded by social insurance, central government, communities and the federal states according to the regulations of the article 15a agreement of the Federal Constitutional Act. The transferal of the resources for hospital care from the health insurance funds to the health care agencies in the federal states is performed based on a defined distribution key. In the area of health insurance financial resources are not allocated to regions but to the individual funds which generate them autonomously by collecting insurance contributions. Contribution rates are defined by law, the right of budgeting (passing a resolution on the annual estimate and the annual report of the management board (Vorstand)) is, according to § 433 ASVG duty of the legislative organ of the insurance fund, the general assembly (Generalversammlung). 410 Federal Ministry of Finance (2006). Budget 2006, Figures – Background – interrelationships, accessed at https://www.bmf.gv.at/Budget/Web_Zusammenhaenge_2006.pdf. on 20/06/2006 411 Article 15a agreement of the Austrian constitution, Article 11, Duties of the federal health care agency LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 132 5.2.3 Decisions about capital investments Expenses for investments in the area of inpatient care are met by the hospital carriers, which are usually the federal states or Federation.412 In their capacity of owners of hospitals the federal states cover expenses for investments and maintenance, furthermore the daily running costs. The Federation renders financial allowances to the hospitals according to § 57 KAKuG and, in the case of university hospitals, substitutes any additional costs resulting from the construction, design and expansion of necessities resulting from teaching. The latter costs are called “klinischer Mehraufwand”, additional clinical expenses. In the area of social insurance the management board is responsible for the management of the insurance fund (§ 434 ASVG), whereby certain duties may be delegated. Further details are stated in the statutes of the individual insurance funds. According to § 436 ASVG the control assembly (Kontrollversammlung) of the individual insurance fund is responsible for the audit of the financial activities (Gebarung), including the examination of accounting and cash administration procedures (Buch- und Kassaführung). The management board necessitates the consent of the control assembly in order to perform permanent assessments. Based on § 437 para.2, a resolution on changes in real estate, especially on the construction or enlargement of buildings also requires the approval of the control assembly, the same is applicable to decisions on the construction of institutions dedicated to administration, medical care, dental care, inpatient care, preventive services for adolescents and adults, treatment of accidents, for rehabilitation, for measures for health promotion, for disease prevention or health care examinations, in own or foreign buildings as well as for rebuilding in case this is linked to a change in the purpose of use. Maintenance or overhauling activities as well as replacement of the inventory do not necessitate the consent of the control assembly, only if there is a causal relationship to the above mentioned projects. 5.2.4 Hospital planning An important planning instrument for all sectors of care, based on article 4 of the 15a B-VG agreement, is the Austrian Structural Plan for Health (Österreichischer Strukturplan Gesundheit, ÖSG) passed on December 16, 2005. The plan replaces the Austrian Hospital and Major Equipment Plan (Österreichischer Krankenanstalten- und Großgeräteplan, ÖKAP and ÖGGP). It represents a mandatory Austria-wide basis for the integrated planning of the care structure in the Austrian health system and covers the areas of inpatient and outpatient care as well as rehabilitation and nursing interfaces. The planning for services offered is set out up to a planning horizon of 2010. Therein Austria is split into four overall care zones which are, in turn, divided up into a further 32 care regions. The federal states have developed detailed plans based on the ÖSG, which sets out the basic conditions. The last agreed status of the ÖKAP/ÖGGP was evaluated up to mid 2005 and remained effective until the end of 2005. An important achievement for social insurance is that, for the first time, the Hauptverband was given a formal right to participate in the development of planning guidelines. An essential difference to the ÖKAP/GGP is that the ÖSG aspires a nationwide planning of health care provision according to groups of diagnosis and services, going away from a planning based on beds or specialties in the direction of displaying the provision of whole regions.413 Statements for expected numbers of services are provided. Planning of major equipment is an integrated part of the planning of service provision and is not carried out separately. Federal states, social health insurance funds and hospital carriers receive more possibilities of influencing the design of health care provision due to the fact that the planning procedures have to be handled amicably.414 412 Fuentes, A., Wurzel, E., Wörgötter, A. (2006). ″Reforming federal fiscal relations in Austria.″ OECD Economics department Working paper No.474, pp. 1-34 413 32 health care regions (based on the NUTS III regions), these are allocated to four health care zones (West, North, East and South) 414 Federal Ministry of Health and Women (BMGF) (2006). Advantages resulting from the Austrian Structural Plan for Health (ÖSG), accessed at http://www.bmgf.gv.at/cms/site/attachments/4/1/1/CH0118/CMS1091614011590/oesg_2005.doc on 20/0672006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 133 The provision of services is linked to the fulfillment of quality criteria (incl. minimum number of consultations and accessibility) whereby the majority of the quality criteria pertaining to structure still comply with those in the ÖKAP of 2003. Also part of the new ÖSG is capacity planning at a regional level for hospitals financed by the agencies for health care in the federal states and an up to date plan for large scale medical equipment. The ÖSG is constantly being revised and developed further. The aim is an integrated care plan. That means that areas of health care beyond those of acute hospitals are to be included in planning, e.g. medical care for outpatients, additional inpatient and outpatient rehabilitation. The ÖSG 2006 provides basic planning directives at federal state level. It is then the duty of the federal states, hospital agencies, and social insurance funds to undertake the detailed planning. This development allows the individual players greater room for manoeuvre whereupon it is hoped that integrated planning will result.415 As has been the practice up to now, sanction measures will come into operation in cases of a deviation from the terms of the Austrian Structural Plan (see articles 35 and 36 of the agreement). For implementation of the health plan the federation uses the services of the Austrian Institute for Health Care (Österreichisches Bundesinstitut für Gesundheitswesen, ÖBIG). See also section on the regulation of the provision of health care. 5.2.5 Geographical differences in per capita health expenditures In Austria geographical differences in per capita health expenditures exist, data or research on the topic is however very limited. Moreover it is extremely difficult to get data as it is considered highly sensitive. When performing an analysis it is crucial to also keep in mind supply side factors such as variations in the amount of services provided or in costs which may originate in these differences. Using the service information system of social insurance (Leistungsinformationssystem, LIVE) it is possible to assign the cost for services to the place of residence of the insured. Results of comparative analysis should be treated with great caution as the systematics of data collection may vary for the individual health insurance funds. In principle these analysis can be performed, however there is room for improvement and a lot of future potential. In the course of the activities of the working group “risk adjustment” (at the regional sickness fund of Salzburg, founded in the context of the re-organization of the equalization fund of the regional health insurance funds) various analyses were undertaken. These could be used within social insurance to analyse differences in per capita spending. When looking at the expenditure of different sickness funds the following becomes apparent. Great variations between the funds in terms of expenditure per insured/beneficiary do exist. In 2005 the costs per insured (for medicines) were lowest at the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA), being €284.23 per insured and highest at the occupational sickness funds, amounting to €502.05 per insured for medicines. On average the costs per insured (for medicines) of all sickness funds was situated at € 337.92. Costs per prescription varied between €17.48 (sickness fund of the farmers) and €24.20 (Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business). Costs per insured for medical devices varied between €39.03 (SVA) and €91.62 (regional sickness funds). The costs per prescription were situated in the range of €56.44 (regional sickness funds) and €121.98 (occupational funds). The following funds were above the average of € 63.86: Insurance fund of the 415 Federal Ministry of Health and Women (BMGF) (2006). Advantages resulting from the Austrian Structural Plan for Health (ÖSG), accessed at http://www.bmgf.gv.at/cms/site/attachments/4/1/1/CH0118/CMS1091614011590/oesg_2005.doc on 20/0672006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 134 Austrian Mining and Railway Industry416, Insurance fund of the Austrian Civil Servants, Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA) and the Austrian Social Insurance Fund of the Farmers.417 The fee of a case per billed contract physician in Austria (All billing entities, Verrechnungsstellen, all medical specialties) ranged between €42.38 in Upper Austria and €51.70 in Lower Austria. An above average fee was found for Lower Austria, Vorarlberg, Salzburg, Carinthia, Burgenland and Tyrol. The average fee per billed physician, in € 1,000, varied between €193.54 in Carinthia and €219.14 in Lower Austria. The average fees per physician were above the average of €204.62 (all § 2 funds) for the billing entities of Lower Austria, Salzburg, Tyrol, Styria and Vorarlberg.418 As already mentioned, huge regional variations in per capita expenditure do exist. However it is very difficult to find evidence related to the variations as data is highly sensitive and access is very restrictive. In the course of the calculation of health expenditure based on the system of health accounts, it is in future planned to calculate expenditures not only on a national but also on a regional level. 416 Since January 2005 merged with the insurance fund of the Austrian Railway Industry. The new fund is the Insurance fund for the Austrian Railway and Mining industries 417 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2006). Statistical handbook of Austrian social insurance 2006. Vienna 418 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2006). Ärztekostenstatistik, Yearly results 2005, finalised 31. August 2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 135 6. TECHNICAL EFFICIENCY There is considerable controversy surrounding the development of an appropriate measure of efficiency in a complex human service sector like health. Economic theory presents one of the main measures of efficiency as technical efficiency, which is concerned with outputs, and not the distribution of those outputs (see section on allocative efficiency). It can be argued that efficiency can be broadly ascertained through an examination of the resources committed to the health system – costs and utilization rates.419 Others have attempted to generate a single measure of efficiency, or productivity of the health system. Health system productivity can be defined as the level of output generated by a given set of inputs. The United Kingdom has been innovative in developing a measure of health system productivity attempting to incorporate elements of quality of care into the measurement of the output of the system – the NHS. The quality indicators that have been used include survival rates, waiting times, patient experiences, and longerterm survival rates for myocardial infarction. These quality indicators are combined with more objective indicators of output such as activity levels at various levels of the system. This is still a premature attempt at analysing performance, but with further work should provide some insight into the costs and benefits of the NHS. Using data from the OECD, one study examines the extent different countries use their health care resources efficiently to achieve favourable health outcomes.420 By measuring health outcomes with life expectancy and infant mortality, some countries were found to be using their healthcare inputs efficiently to produce its current levels of both outputs, including France, Greece, Ireland, Norway, Spain, Sweden and the UK. Other countries were performing better for infant mortality than for life expectancy, including Denmark, Finland and Portugal. Put another way, these three countries could produce higher levels of life expectancy given their level of inputs and current social environment (measured by school expectancy, income inequality and population characteristics). Other countries were found to be inefficient for both outputs, including Austria, Belgium, Germany, the Netherlands and Switzerland. Overall, these findings provide an alternative method of calculating outputs of health systems in a way that can provide insight into making possible improvements, either by increasing resources, or by maintaining the same level of resources and improving efficiency. However it is important to note that this method of measuring efficiency is based on aggregate measures of spending and health outcomes, therefore should be interpreted with caution. 6.1 Administrative costs It is also worthwhile examining differences in administrative costs across different countries’ health systems which may give an indication of relative (in)efficiency. Administrative costs reflect part of health care funding that is not directly related to improving health. Included in these costs are the planning, management, regulation, and collection of funds and handling of insurance claims.421 Table 6.1 shows that on average social health insurance countries tend to have higher administrative costs (i.e. Germany, Luxembourg, the Netherlands), with costs in Austria being relatively lower and closer to those of taxfunded systems. The lower level of administrative costs in Austria and France could be attributed to the lack of choice permitted between sickness funds, with the exception of Luxembourg.422 419 Figueras et al., "Patterns and Performance in Social Health Insurance Systems." D Retzlaff-Roberts, C.F Chang, and R.M Rubin, "Technical Efficiency in the Use of Health Care Resources: A Comparison of OECD Countries," Health Policy 69, no. 1 (2004). 421 Figueras et al., "Patterns and Performance in Social Health Insurance Systems." 422 Ibid. 420 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 136 Table 6.1 Total expenditure on health administration and insurance as a percentage of total health expenditure in selected European countries, 1990, 1995, 2000-3 Country 1990 1995 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Austria 3.8 4.1 3 2.5 2.5 2.6 Belgium 6.3 Czech Republic 3 2.6 2.7 2.5 3.2 Denmark 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.9 1 1.9 2.1 Finland 2 2.3 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.2 France 1.6 1.7 1.9 1.9 7.8 7.7 7.5 Germany 6.3 5.3 5.4 5.3 5.5 5.6 Hungary 2.8 1.9 1.6 1.6 Italy 0.4 0.3 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.3 Luxembourg 3.4 3 2 11 9.6 Netherlands 4.9 4.5 4.9 4.6 4.3 4.3 4.4 Poland 2.2 1.4 2.4 Portugal 1.4 1.3 1.1 1.1 1.8 Slovak Republic 2.9 2.6 0.6 0.4 Spain 2.7 2.5 2.5 2.5 3.2 3.2 Sweden 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.5 Source: OECD health data 2006 Note: countries selected based on availability of data 6.1.2 Administrative costs in Austria Compared to other European countries Austria spends a high share of its health care expenditures on hospitals (43%).423 The costs of hospitals funded by public sources (nine health funds of the federal states) amounted to around € 8,911 million in 2005. Costs doubled in all federal states between 1991 and 2004. The increase over time lies slightly above the consumer price index. Increasing rates for costs could be reduced by mid of the Nineties. Between 1997 and 2004 the federal states experienced increases of 23% (Vienna) to 38% (Lower Austria, Burgenland). More than half of the hospital costs are staff costs. The increase in cost is also related to the employment of better qualified personnel (doctors). Costs for medicines make up about 5% of total costs, over the past years strong increases have taken place. About three quarters of the costs are for inpatient care, roughly 13% for outpatient care and 10% for other areas of care, partially not directly related to the hospital duties. 423 Hofmarcher, M.M., Lietz, C., Schnabl, A. (2005). ″Inefficiency in Austrian inpatient care: identifying ailing providers based on DEA results.″ Central European Journal of Operations Research, to be published LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 137 Figure 6.1 Costs in hospitals funded by the federal health funds 1991-2004 (1991 = 100) Line= total costs for hospitals, triangle= personnel costs, circle= costs for medicines Source: BMGF (2006). Hospitals in figures accessed at www. bmgf.gv.at on 15/06/2006424 Expenditure of social health insurance for administration is very low. In 2005 it figured about 2.93% of total expenditure. Table 6.2 Administration costs of social health insurance Absolute % of total expenditure Index % change to the previous year 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 366 343 358 327 351 3.76 3.37 3.40 3.02 3.12 100.00 93.72 97.81 89.34 95.90 -6.28 4.37 -8.66 7.34 2005 346 2.93 94.54 -1.42 Source: Handbook of Austrian social insurance 2006, own calculations 424 Source: BMGF: Hospital-Cost accounting (hospitals funded by the federal health funds) Statistics Austria: Consumer price index LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 138 6.2 Physical and human resources Another way of investigating efficiency is to look at broad measures of resource capacity and also utilization rates. For instance, one would predict that the countries that spend more (per capita, or as a proportion of GDP) would also have higher absolute levels of physical resources such as hospital beds and medical technology. For instance, comparing countries with social health insurance systems with those funded through taxation, one can see a trend emerge. Social health insurance systems appear to be, on average, more expensive that the tax-funded systems, and they also have higher population-adjusted numbers of expensive diagnostic equipment (CT and MRI). In fact, as shown in Table 6.3, Austria has the second highest level of CT scanners per capita, and highest level of MRIs. Table 6.3 MRI and CT units per million population in selected European countries, 2003 CT scanners/ million MRI scanners/ million population population Belgium (2002) Austria Luxembourg Italy Greece (2002) Denmark Germany (2002) Sweden (1999) Finland Spain Portugal Czech Republic Slovak Republic France Hungary Poland United Kingdom (2001) 28.8 27.2 26.7 24 17.1 14.5 14.2 14.2 14 13 12.8 12.6 8.7 8.4 6.9 6.3 5.8 6.6 13.5 11.1 11.6 2.3 9.1 6 7.9 12.8 7.3 3.9 2.4 2 2.8 2.6 1 5.2 Source: OECD health data 2006 Turning to human resources, one can see quite significant variability across countries in the supply of physicians and nurses (Figure 6.2). Higher density of physicians has been shown to be associated with better health outcomes, and better responsiveness, in terms of lower waiting times.425 425 Steven Simoens and Jeremy Hurst, "The Supply of Physician Services in OECD Countries," (Paris: Organization for economic co-operation and development, 2006). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 139 Figure 6.2 Physician and nurse supply per 1000 population in Western Europe, 2003 Source: WHO Health for All 2005 Also there appears to be a weak positive association between physician density and health spending (as a percent of GDP) across OECD countries.426 It is more likely, however, that spending would correlated with both physician remuneration method (i.e. fee-for-service, versus salary and capitation methods) and the number of practising physicians per population (Table 6.4). 426 Ibid. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 140 Table 6.4 Relationship between physician density, remuneration and expenditure Source: Simoens and Hurst 2006 Within the hospital sector, efficiency could be broadly ascertained by examining average length of stay and occupancy rates. In the past few decades there has been a consistent trend towards shorter length of stays in almost every OECD country (Figure 6.3). Figure 6.3 Average length of inpatient stay in selected European countries 25 20 15 10 5 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2003 Austria Czech Republic Denmark Finland France Germany Hungary Ireland Italy Poland Portugal Spain Sweden United Kingdom 2004 Source: OECD Health data 2006 6.2.1 Hospital capacity in Austria The Federation and the federal states already agreed on reducing the number of acute beds mid of the eighties. This was made possible by shifting care to extramural levels of care as well as by a decline in the average length of stay. The reduction is especially visible for hospitals funded by the federal health funds, which provide a majority of the acute beds. Beds in hospitals not funded by the federal health funds are often beds for long-term care which is why the reduction in length of stay was not so dominant. Discrepancies are mostly due to changes in the legal status of the hospitals (hospitals are not any more part LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 141 of hospital statistics) or to the building and enlargement of rehabilitation centres. Beds per 100,000 inhabitants declined from 9.89 in 1991 to 7.73 in 2004. The decline in beds between 1991 and 2004 notably affected the states of Vienna (-32%), Vorarlberg (29%) and Upper Austria (-16%).427 Figure 6.4 Beds in Austrian hospitals 1991-2004 (1991 = 100) line= Austria total, diamond= hospitals funded by the federal health funds, circle=hospitals not funded by the federal health funds Number of beds 2004: hospitals funded by the federal health funds: 49,130 (77.7%), Hospitals not funded by the federal health funds: 14,076 (22.3%). Source: BMGF (2006). Hospitals in figures accessed at www. bmgf.gv.at on 15/06/2006428 In comparison to the European average Austria has a high density of hospital beds, especially for acute care. Over the past 15 years a significant decline has taken place. However Austria’s number of acute beds remains far above the European average. The Czech Republic, Hungary, Luxembourg and Slovakia have similar values. In the figure below only those European countries are shown for which values for both years are available. 427 BMGF (2006). Hospitals in figures accessed at www. bmgf.gv.at on 15/06/2006, own calculations Source: BMGF Hospital Statistics (hospitals funded by the federal health funds), annual report (hospitals not funded by the federal health funds), reports on diagnosis and services (hospitals funded by the federal health funds) – average length of stay (all BMGF), Statistics Austria: Extrapolation of the population, yearly averages 1991–2004 (status: 23.05.2005) 428 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 142 Figure 6.5 Acute beds per 100,000 inhabitants Acute beds per 100,000 inhabitants Countries EU Sweden Slovenia Slovakia Portugal Luxembourg Italy Ireland Hungary France Finland Estonia Denmark Czech Republic Cyprus Belgium Austria 0 200 400 600 800 1000 Beds per 100,000 1990 last available Source: WHO Health for All, 2006. 6.2.2 Substitution policies in Austria Generic substitution by pharmacists is not permitted in Austria, the views of the stakeholders (Pharmig, Medical Chamber, social insurance, patient lawyer) regarding the introduction of an aut idem regulation 429 are mixed.430 Health insurance funds undertake a range of efforts to increase the share of generics prescribed, partially employing financial incentives to motivate physicians to prescribe more generics. The share of generics prescribed (of total prescriptions) at the different sickness funds varied between 9 and 15% (number of prescriptions), in terms of costs of prescribed medicines generics accounted for 6-10%. In the segment in which substitution through generics is possible the share of prescribed generics amounted to 30-55% of all prescriptions and to 20-40% of total costs. More information on strategies used by the health insurance funds to reduce expenditure on medicines can be found in the report by Mossialos, Ziniel, Merkur, Walley und McGuire on “Public Policy and the Austrian Pharmaceutical Market: Options for Reform”.431 With respect to substitution of personnel in the health care sector a tendency of patients to directly consult a medical specialist instead of a general practitioner can be observed. Areas of responsibility of physicians partially shift to other health care professionals, duties of general practitioners will be extended, they will 429 The physician does not prescribe a certain medication/drug but only the generic substance, doses and mode of application. The pharmacists then chooses the cheapest from a group of medications which are comparable in terms of quality 430 Mossialos E, et al. (2005). Public Policy and the Austrian Pharmaceutical Market: Options for Reform. London School of Economics and Political Sciences, LSE Health and Social Care. London. 431 ibid LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 143 for instance be responsible for administrating and monitoring disease management programs. The provision of services i.e the billing of services is usually based on the fact that the physician provides the service personally. The extent to which nurses or medical assistants (e.g. dental assistants) perform medical tasks is handled very differently, normally however responsibilities are separated very strictly. A couple of studies have compared the cost of providing treatment in or outside of the hospital. Before results are presented it is emphasised how complicated a comparison of service provision through a physician in a surgery or through a hospital outpatient department is. With respect to interpretation of results one should be well aware which parameters were chosen for the comparison in order to judge if the comparison is reliable or valid. In 2001 Laimböck compared treatment costs (per patient visit) of outpatient departments in hospitals (only looking at general outpatient departments) with treatment costs of medical specialists in practices and concluded that the general hypothesis of treatment being cheaper outside of the hospital cannot be confirmed. Costs per visit of a general outpatient department are lower than fees of medical specialists with a contract with social insurance. Comparing the cost of individual services in outpatient departments and in practices of medical specialists shows a similar level of costs. When comparing two comparable institutions the treatment costs are lower in the outpatient department. It was not possible to taken into consideration that the illnesses of patients in outpatient departments are likely to be more severe than those of patients consulting medical specialists in their practices.432 The results and the data used by Laimböck were discussed and criticised, arguing that they were partially outdated or compared values which should not be compared with each other. Furthermore they could not be extrapolated to the whole of Austria as they only represented a small region in the federal state of Tyrol.433 In 2001 the regional sickness fund of Vienna compared treatment costs in the Hanusch hospital434 (outpatient departments) with treatment costs of medical specialists in practices435. Overall treatment in outpatient departments was slightly cheaper (by about 11%). Treatment was cheaper in the following outpatient departments436: internal medicine, heart, gastro, diabetes, surgery, accident, rheuma, otorhinolaryngology. Treatment in the following outpatient departments was calculated to be more expensive than treatment by medical specialists in their practices: dermatology, children, ophthalmology, urology and orthopaedics. Hofmarcher, Riedel and Röhrling437 also analysed the question if treatment costs were higher in hospital or outside the hospital and concluded that a potential for substitution between outpatient departments in hospitals and practices of medical specialists does exist, however the scope of this potential is not clear. Furthermore they urge that a simple comparison of average costs is not valid and that the aims of service provision of each provider have to be taken into consideration. The regional sickness fund of Vienna analysed the relationship between the number of physicians (density, § 2 contract physicians per 1,000 inhabitants in one district) and the number of hospital visits (inpatient admissions per 1,000 inhabitants of one district) as well as the association between the density of contract physicians and the number of visits to outpatient departments.438 Pazourek calculated correlation 432 Laimböck, M. (2001). ″Analysis and comparison of treatment costs in outpatient departments and practices of medical specialists.″, received from Laimböck via email; Laimböck, M. (2000). Social health insurance between state, monopoly and competition. Berenkamp 433 Hampel, R. (2001).″Please, respectable comparisons!″ Ärztezeitung 21, pp. 13-14 434 Integrated hospital of the regional sickness fund of Vienna 435 Using the study by Laimböck as a reference for calculation methods 436 First (considerably cheaper, about 62%), last (a little bit cheaper, about 8.9%). 437 Hofmarcher, M., Riedel, M., Röhrling, G. (2001).″ Focus: Doctor's Practice or Outpatient Department: One case is not one case.". Health System Watch IV, supplement of the Austrian journal of social insurance Soziale Sicherheit, pp. 11-23. 438 Pazourek, J. (2001). Association between physician density, hospital visits and visits to outpatient departments–an analysis of the regional sickness fund of Vienna. Presentation given in August 2001, Management Summary. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 144 coefficients (Pearson) and used regression plots for visualisation. The hypothesis, that the higher the density of (contract) physicians per district, the lower the number of hospital admissions in the district, could be rejected, the hypothesis that the higher the density of contract physicians, the higher the number of hospital visits was supported. Regarding the association between physician density (contract physicians per 1,000 inhabitants) and the number of visits to outpatient departments (per 1,000 inhabitants) the hypothesis “the higher the density of contract physicians per federal state, the lower the number of visits to outpatient departments in the federal state could be rejected. However the hypothesis “the higher the density of contract physicians the higher the number of outpatient visits could be confirmed. In the same presentation Pazourek showed that most patients accessed outpatient departments via the following routes:439 - Inpatients (47%) - Referred by physicians outside of the hospital (27%) - Final outpatient treatment (12%) - Came by themselves, emergency (6%) - Came by themselves, no emergency (5%) - Brought by ambulance (3%) Based on the results of his analysis, Pazourek concluded that an increase in the number of contract physicians would not result in a steering (substitution) effect but would increase the number of visits to outpatient departments. A co-payment for patients when accessing outpatient care (introduced in 2001, abolished in 2003440) would not steer consumption as patients rarely decide themselves to visit an outpatient department but are usually referred during an inpatient stay or by a physician outside the hospital. 6.2.3 Physician career paths in Austria After successful completion of studies of Human Medicine university graduates have various possibilities. One is to complete post-doctorate training (Turnus), either in the form of a three year training to qualify as a General Practitioner, or a six year training to qualify as a Specialist/Consultant (these are minimum time periods). Training places are sites recognised by the Medical Chamber. Over the past years there has, in part, been a significant shortage of training places in hospitals. Because it is often very difficult to get a consultant training placement upon completion of their studies many of those graduates interested first decide to enter the training to become a General Practitioner, during which they apply for Consultant positions. Subsequent training for qualification as a specialist takes around 5 years, as parts of the previous General Practitioner training may be counted as credit. A doctor who has completed his training for Consultant is called an intern/assistant doctor (Assistenzarzt). During training he can also work as a ward physician, this function can equally be performed by a General Practitioner. Professional eligibility for General Practitioner or Consultant can only be obtained after compliance with certain pre-requisites has been verified, e.g. evidence of having completed the minimum training period, a fully completed positive report (Rasterzeugnisse), as well as, a positive examination result.441 With completion of the examination the doctor receives the jus practicandi which, aside from the official right to independent practice, is required for freelance activity, undertaking stand-in work, precautionary health care examinations, counselling, certification/expert opinions etc. At this point in time the doctor has the option 439 OEBIG in Pazourek, J. (2001). Association between physician density, hospital visits and visits to outpatient departments–an analysis of the regional sickness fund of Vienna. Presentation given in August 2001, Management Summary. 440 Mossialos E, et al. (2005). Public Policy and the Austrian Pharmaceutical Market: Options for Reform. London School of Economics and Political Sciences, LSE Health and Social Care. London. 441 Details on examinations for specialists see Chapter 6 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 145 of going into employment (e.g. in a hospital, nursing home, sanatorium, outpatient clinic), to be selfemployed (home doctor442, private practice, private doctor, contract doctor), or of joining a group practice, a cooperative praxis, or long term substitution, etc. After taking their exam very few General Practitioners (GPs) remain in hospitals. A GP, who continues to work in the hospital, is called an assistant doctor (Sekundararzt). Most GPs work in their own individual practices. Establishment of a practice is linked with numerous pre-conditions and brings with it many obligations which are not covered in detail at this point. If the qualified Consultant continues to work at a hospital then the next stage in the hierarchy is the position of Oberarzt (senior physician/head of department), although actually the Oberarzt is a description of status and not an official title according to the doctors law. The position of Oberarzt is awarded based on professional qualification, length of service, and possibly upon the recommendation of the head of department. The next step is the “first Oberarzt” or “first senior physician”, who is usually appointed by the chief physician (Primararzt) and is chosen for this position based on length of service. The “first senior physician” is at the same time the deputy for the chief physician. Technically the position of Chief Physician is, after Consultant, the next step in the hospital hierarchy. The Chief Physician is responsible for a whole specialist department. In order to become Chief Physician it is not necessary to sit a special examination. The position is linked with specific professional qualifications (Consultant in the specialisation of the department to be led), professional experience as well as evidence of other required competencies. Criteria for the job advertisement are specified by the employer. Of course medical graduates can also follow other career paths (medical/non medical) and work amongst other things in public health services, in research, in establishments of the social insurance funds, in the pharmaceutical industry, consultancy, as occupational medical doctors, and as school doctors. With the exception of the first (public services, see the following section) these areas are not gone covered in greater detail in this report. 6.3 Provider payment methods The methods used to pay health care providers create powerful incentives that affect provider behaviour and the efficiency, equity and quality outcomes of health system financing. Specifically, these payment methods can be used to influence the price and quantity of health care. In the health service, there are three basic methods of physician payment: fee-for-service, salary and capitation. There are many variations of these payment systems, but the basic principles remain. Fee-for-service is an agreed upon value for a specific service which is to be provided. The incentive is to provide the best service at a reasonable cost to maintain the confidence of patients. Fee-for-service payment works well when there is an adequate supply of providers, minimal interference in the negotiation of prices, and freedom to choose the provider. It fails when providers attempt to control supply and demand (cartels) or when insurers set prices at a level too low for providers to survive (rent controls). Regulations can be implemented to prevent these examples of potential failures. Salary is the payment of a negotiated amount of money for a fixed period of time, within which providers are commitment to providing services. The number of patients seen, services provided, and the cost of services do not affect the payment. Legislation can be in place to cover overtime pay and holiday pay based on time worked. However, salaries are still linked to services since the payment for salaries must come from the payment for the service to the third party or through taxation in a public system. 442 A doctor who does not have an own practice or is employed by a hospital but practices medicine from his private residence (e.g. compiling expert opinions, standing in for other doctors, etc.). He needs to register at the Medical Chamber. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 146 Capitation is the payment of a set amount of money to the provider to insure that services are provided to the user in a given time period. The provider agrees to provide all agreed services and bares the risk that the negotiated amount will cover costs and leave a profit. The user agrees to obtain the agreed services only from the designated provider unless additional money is paid out. These different physician remuneration methods have different inherent incentives (see Table 6.5). Table 6.5 Doctor Payment Systems and incentive effects443 Payment type Definition Fee-forservice Salary Payment for each medical act Payment per unit of time input (e.g. per month) Payment per patient for care within a given time period (e.g. a year) Capitation Incentive to increase activity Incentive to decrease activity Yes No Incentive to shift patients’ costs to others No Incentive to target the poor Controls cost of doctors’ employment Maybe* No No Yes Yes No Yes No Yes Yes No Yes *If fee-for-service payments for treating poor patients exceed those for treating middle classes The established analyses of payment mechanisms focus on the balancing of risk aversion with moral hazard.444,445 The combination of retrospective (i.e. fee-for-service) and prospective (i.e. capitation, salaries) payment methods under the need to balance conflicting incentives falls within the scope of the economic literature on principal-agent relationships as well as the literature on optimal contracts in the context of multi-task agency relationships.446 There is inconclusive evidence on the link between targeted financial incentives and the behaviour of individual doctors, particularly in relation to quality improvements. Methodological problems persist with attributing complex behavioural changes to particular interventions, and with assessing the spillover effects of interventions onto behaviours other than those incentivised.447 Other challenges with assessing the effects of financial incentives on physician behaviour include a number of factors such as the observations that beyond the economic rewards of financial incentives, doctors are motivated by other goals (e.g. improving chronic disease management).448 Also, doctors may have a targeted income beyond which they are no longer motivated by financial incentives (no linear relationship between incentives and impact).449 Despite these challenges there are some important lessons regarding financial incentives: they are more effective if they are owned by their target audience and aligned to professional values; they should be focused more on technical aspects and less on indeterminate aspects of professional practice; and professional motivation is 443 A Maynard and K Bloor, "Do Those Who Pay the Piper Call the Tune?," Health Policy Matters 8 (2003). K.M. Eisenhardt, "Agency Theory: An Assessment and Review," Academy of Management Review 14 ,, no. 4 (1989). 445 D Sappington, "Incentives in Principal-Agent Relationships," Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 2 (1991). 446 J.C Robinson et al., "The Alignment and Blending of Payment Incentives within Physician Organizations," Health Services Research 39, no. 5 (2004). 447 M Marshall and S Harrison, "It's About More Than Money: Financial Incentives and Internal Motivation," Quality and Safety in Health Care 14, no. 1 (2005). 448 A Spooner, A Chapple, and M Roland, "What Makes British General Practitioners Take Part in a Quality Improvement Scheme?," Journal of Health Services Research and Policy 6 (2001). 449 J Rizzo and D Blumenthal, "Is the Target Income Hypothesis an Economic Heresy?," Medical Care Research and Review 53 (1996). 444 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 147 more likely to be damaged by overly bureaucratic schemes. Thus, it would be inappropriate to link financial rewards to complex diagnostic processes or to the psychosocial aspects of care provision. In Western European countries, the three methods discussed above are the main approaches for paying providers. In the public sector most primary and outpatient care doctors are paid on a salaried or capitation basis, or a combination of the two. Capitation payments are predominantly used in Italy, the Netherlands, and the UK. Alternatively, fee-for-service payments prevail in some countries, namely Austria, Belgium, France and Germany. This method of payment is also the norm for privately delivered primary and outpatient care. Several studies have found supportive evidence for actual effects of payment method on physician behaviour.15,450,451 Therefore, it has been proposed that a mixed payment scheme, which includes elements of all three mechanisms helps to moderate these negative incentives. In consideration of the incentives inherent in the main methods of physician payment, some alternative models have been devised. These include performance-based reimbursement in Sweden and the GP contract in the UK. In the United States, experimentation with physician payment methods that incentivise physicians to expand the provision of preventive services, improve clinical outcomes and enhance patient safety and satisfaction are collectively called “pay-for-performance” programs. These programs are based on the premise that the structure of payment methods may not facilitate (or even prevent) the actions needed to systematically improve quality of care.452 Explicitly stated quality standards can act as objectives to which health care providers commit. The inclusion of metrics within a contract, by which standards can be measured, helps in analyzing adherence to quality specifications. Quality specifications can be structure, process or outcome oriented thereby differing in what they measure, but all enacted to meet the goal of quality provision. Structural mechanisms involve making it compulsory for providers to build into contracts means by which quality levels can be assured. Process mechanisms operate to monitor patient outcomes through specific protocols and guidelines, such as the percentage of patients vaccinated, or guarantee a specified volume of services. Outcome targets are similar to process goals in their use of guidelines except they are based on results of treatment rather than actual treatment levels. However, a lack of information hinders purchasers’ understanding of the quality level that they are paying for in some types of health services. Incorporating a broad array of quality measures in an incentive program, appears to be an attempt to deal with the “multi-tasking” problem, such that if providers face a number of tasks and resources are limited, then effort will be allocated toward those tasks that are explicitly rewarded, taking resources away from other activities. By choosing to attach financial rewards to a larger set of tasks, payers can elevate and protect key priorities from these negative spill-over effects. However, the dimensions of care that will receive the most attention will be those that are most easily measured and not necessarily those that are most valued. Hospital payment systems Within the public hospital sector, salary payments are widespread although fee-for-service has been customarily used in some countries with a move towards a case-based payment system according to diagnosis related groups (DRGs). Most countries in Western Europe have moved to a performance-based approach, using some combination of case-mix adjusted DRGs and/or global budgets. Within this general framework, there is some diversity of approaches to payment for inpatient services, and many have developed to meet cost-containment objectives. 450 C Chaix-Couturier et al., "Effects of Financial Incentives on Medical Practice: Results from a Systematic Review of the Literature and Methodological Issues," International Journal for Quality in Health Care 12, no. 2 (2000). 451 T Gosden, F Forland, and I.S Kristiansen, Cochrane Review: Capitation, Salary, Fee-for-Service and Mixed System of Payment: Effects on Behaviour of Primary Care Physicians., vol. The Cochrane Library, Issue 2. (Chichester, UK: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., 2006). 452 Institute of Medicine, Crossing the Quality Chasm: A New Health System for the 21st Century. (Washington, DC: The National Academies Press, 2001). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 148 Case-based payment can be used for inpatient care, with hospitals being paid an inclusive flat sum for a patient’s treatment according to a DRG. DRGs are used in the United States’ Medicare program for the elderly and setting part or the whole of hospital budgets in Austria, Ireland, Finland, Portugal, Spain and Sweden.453 Budgets can take different forms. ‘Hard’ budgets use penalties for over-spending and may also provide reward for under-spending. If the budget is used to reimburse fee-for-service providers, the fees can be automatically adjusted retrospectively to make sure that total expenditure remains within budget. The rewards can involve retention by the agent of some or all of any surplus made. Alternatively, with target or ‘shadow’ budgets, a record is kept of the costs of the transactions undertaken, but no immediate penalties are applied and overspending is automatically met. Budgets do not dictate specific practice patterns and allow greater doctor autonomy than some other controls. They may also give the medical profession a motivating rationale to develop, support and even implement clear clinical standards and other strategies to achieve lower volumes. Doctors may have a strong incentive to monitor practice patterns for appropriateness. Budgets can play an important role in health reforms that include decentralization of the decision-making process in the health system and devolution of responsibilities on resource allocation to local hospital managers. Countries in Western Europe provide an interesting example of convergence towards a mixed payment system, for funding hospital services. The majority of countries currently use some form of case-mix system, original or an adaptation of the DRG system, often with a global budget cap. Each system has adapted the specifics of the case-mix measure and/or the application to fit within the local funding framework and to address the objectives prioritized within the local hospital environment. There is no definitive best way of remunerating providers. The method chosen to pay providers depends on the goals of policy-makers. There is greater potential success for mixed/blended payment systems with performance management when activity is monitored. Capitation and salary systems create effective cost control, but with the possibility of under-serving patients; however, if these systems are accompanied by constrained evidence-based and cash limited systems of fee-for-service, they can increase activity and may improve quality if accompanied by local micro-management. Aligning providers’ financial incentives with quality goals may be a necessary precursor to the improvement of health care purchasing. Quality-incentive programs should be viewed as part of a broader strategy of promoting health care quality through measuring and reporting performance, providing technical assistance and evidence-based guidelines, and increasingly, giving consumers incentives to select higherquality providers (where they have choice) and proactively manage their own health. Payment of pharmacists The role of pharmacists are becoming more clinical in addition to assisting in controlling pharmaceutical expenditure when permitted to undergo generic and therapeutic substitution, and when there are incentives to practice economical dispensing. One radically new role for pharmacists in the UK will be as prescribers, responsible for dose adjustment and monitoring in a range of chronic conditions where a doctor has made the diagnosis. Regulation of pharmacists differs across the EU Member States. Some different regulatory practices include controlling community pharmacy ownership and location, setting allowable profit margins, and influencing drug distribution patterns and product selection through different incentives and remuneration methods. The method of paying pharmacists impacts their product selection. Pharmacists receive a fixed fee per item dispensed in Ireland, the Netherlands, Sweden and the UK. In the UK, there is also a fixed reimbursement price on unbranded generics, therefore pharmacists have the incentive to dispense the cheapest suitable 453 G Carrin and P Hanvoravongchai, "Provider Payments and Patient Charges as Policy Tools for Cost-Containment: How Successful Are They in High-Income Countries?," Human Resources for Health 1 (2003). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 149 product and in doing so retain the difference between the purchase price and the reimbursement price. Similar preferential margins to motivate dispensing choice exist in some other EU markets. In Denmark a dispensing budget introduces a collective incentive to dispense economically. Pharmacists in Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Germany, Greece, Italy and Portugal are paid regressive scaled margins or margins that are a fixed percentage of a product’s price. Under this payment method, pharmacists have little incentive to dispense cheaper products. Denmark (since 1991), Finland, France (since 2001) and Spain allow a pharmacist to substitute a generic for a branded preparation, regardless of how the prescription was written. 6.3.1 Provider payment methods in Austria The way health care providers are paid for their efforts can strongly influence their behaviour. Types of reimbursement mechanisms are salary, capitation, fee-for service or blended systems. Each of these entails different incentives for the provider, thus influencing his work. In general the payment of Austrian health care providers is not linked to targets or quality outcomes, leaving room for potential productivity gains. In the next sections the payment of physicians who signed a contract with social insurance, the reimbursement of hospitals and the payment of hospitals doctors is described as well as potential impacts on their behaviour. Payment of physicians in ambulatory care – contract physicians of social insurance Physicians who signed a contract with social health insurance are usually paid by a blended system, which is based on fee-for service payment and supplemented by a capitated payment (per patient, for a certain time span), also called basic reimbursement (Grundleistungsvergütung). Additional benefits (special services, Sonderleistungen) are also reimbursed. Most health insurance funds pay their contract partners a basic capitated fee for a quarter year (3 months), regardless of how many consultations occur within this time span. Thus the risk related to the number of physician visits within a quarter is partially shifted to the doctor. Many sickness funds provide payments per visit (in addition to the initial lump sum and mostly of a limited amount). The height of the capitated payment varies amongst the sickness funds and may also depend on the specialty of the doctor. Special insurance funds (Sonderversicherungsträger), SVA, BVA and VAEB454 pay their contract partners (physicians) by fee-for service payment only, some regional sickness funds have a very low basic reimbursement (Carinthia, Lower Austria) Based on the fact that Austrian physicians are mostly reimbursed by fee-for service payments this would lead to the assumption that they are incentivised to maximise the number of services they provide. In order to counteract this, health insurance funds implement steering mechanisms in their reimbursement catalogues and/or general contracts. Steering instruments applied by most of the insurance funds when reimbursing providers are for instance billing restrictions, capping of benefits provided and degressive payments (price-volume trade-off once a certain volume of benefits is reached). The latter mechanism is used when new benefits are introduced or in case a service is provided very frequently. Billing restrictions are used to ensure a certain quality of the service provided, e.g. a physician is only allowed to bill a service if he provides evidence of having the adequate training or equipment. They are also applied to restrict service provision to certain disease indications, to limit the number of times a certain service is provided within a defined time period or to prevent services being provided in combination with other services. In the case of caps/quotas services are only reimbursed for a certain percentage of cases, e.g. 10%. Reimbursement for preventive services is not linked to the fulfilment of defined targets, such as reaching a certain number of people. The health check up is regulated in a separate general contract and reimbursed on a fee-for service basis. If the reimbursement of services is not linked to the fulfilment of quality targets there is a risk of health care providers reducing the quality of services provided. 454 Self-employed, civil servants, Mining and Railway Industry LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 150 Reimbursement of inpatient care About 40% of Austrian health care expenditure is for hospitals455. Hospitals are funded by social health insurance, the Federation, the federal states, local governments (municipalities), hospital carriers, patients, private health insurance and social welfare. In comparison to the Federation and the federal states, who contribute fixed amounts of money and defined percentages of the income generated by value added tax, social insurance456 pays a lump sum for public hospitals according to § 447 para.1 ASVG. The lump sum covers all services in the areas of inpatient care, part-inpatient care, day-clinical and outpatient care, including those services resulting from technological advances provided by hospitals financed by the health funds in the federal states (Landesgesundheitsfonds).457 Increases in the number of cases (e.g. dialysis) are also considered. This lump sum represents about 42% of the total costs of hospitals financed by the health funds of the federal states and is valorised according to the increase in the income generated through health insurance contribution. In 2005 social health insurance funds spent 3.419 billion Euros on hospital care representing about 34.7% or the income raised by contributions458. Social insurance funds paid 3.384 billion Euros to the health funds in the federal states. The federal states, the legal entities (hospital carriers) and the municipalities are liable for any underfunding of the health funds.459 Considerable regional variations exist. For-profit hospitals i.e. sanatoria which are not funded by the health funds in the federal states are funded based on nationwide, performance-orientated principles. Health insurance funds allocate a yearly prospective amount of 72.67 million Euros to the fund for the private hospitals (PrivatkrankenanstaltenFinanzierungsfonds, PRIKRAF) which is situated in the Chamber of Commerce and was set up in 2002. The distribution of funds by the PRIKRAF is undertaken partially based on days and partially on performance related measures. In addition to funds from social insurance for-profit hospitals receive a major part of their income from private health insurance companies. Funding of private hospitals which are neither funded by the health funds in the federal states nor by the PRIKRAF fund (e.g. military hospitals) is regulated in individual contracts with social insurance. For the Hanusch hospital (regional sickness fund of Vienna) and the accident hospitals special agreements exist. On January 1, 1997 a performance orientated reimbursement system for hospitals, Leistungsorientierte Krankenanstaltenfinanzierung , LKF, was introduced in hospitals funded by the federal health funds. This reimbursement mechanism substituted the existing hospital reimbursement based on undifferentiated daily payments. This step enabled the visualisation of the actual service provision. About half of daily concerns are based on performance orientated funding460 and on countrywide standardized point values per diagnosis related group (LKF core area). This system is complemented by lump sum budgets. The value of each point is not the same in every federal state, it depends on the funds available in the respective health fund of the federal state. Around half of hospital services are reimbursed on the basis of a fee-for services payment by national budgets. This type of payment entails the incentive of increasing the amount of services provided (maximising points) or of engaging in DRG creep.461 455 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 456 Tripold, M. (2005). The Austrian Health Care System 1945 up to the present in Sprenger, M. (Ed.) Public Health in Austria and Europe, , Pabst Science Publishers, Lengerich, 2005 457 Outpatient services provided in the course of the mother-child pass investigations and services explicitly excluded by mutual consent of social insurance and the relevant federal states are not reimbursed 458 Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (2006), Handbook of Austrian Social Insurance 2005. Vienna. 459 Tripold, M. (2005). The Austrian Health Care System 1945 up to the present in Sprenger, M. (Ed.) Public Health in Austria and Europe, , Pabst Science Publishers, Lengerich, 2005 460 Pazourek, J. (2005), ″Hospital funding since 1997.″ Soziale Sicherheit 1, pp. 11-16 461 Hofmarcher, M.M., Patterson, I., Riedel, M., (2002). ″Measuring Hospital Efficiency in Austria–A DEA approach, Health Care Management Science 5, pp. 7-14 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 151 Reimbursement based on case related payments ought to, as a prospective reimbursement system, result in an increase in efficiency by encouraging all groups engaged to be more aware of costs thus leading to a reduction in costs. The LKF system has increased transparency in inpatient care. Implicit standards are defined and due to the case-based payment a relationship between diagnosis and services is established. The Austrian DRG system is characterised by considerable flexibility, amongst other things taking account of medical advances as well as long-term care institutions. Equally it is possible to continuously develop it further.462 The LKF system also includes negative incentives. It motivates health care institutions to admit more patients, to maximise points (DRG creep), to engage in case-splitting and to admit certain ambulatory patients to inpatient wards. Moreover there is an incentive to provide additional services. Further “weaknesses” of the LKF system are the partial lack in depth of the case groups (considering the severity of the disease) and that it is not always possible to distinguish between acute and chronic. There are no incentives for the provision of preventive service. Fragmentation of the health care system is further facilitated (missing interfaces, duplication of services, waiting times, etc.) In addition a stronger competition takes place for expensive DRG groups. Reimbursement of physicians in hospitals Physicians in hospitals are paid by a salary which they receive from the hospital carrier. Usually the salary is paid on a monthly basis and consists of three parts, the basic salary, payments for private patients and payment for on-call work. The type of reimbursement and the amount not only vary amongst the federal states but also depend on the hospital carrier. In some cases doctors working in hospitals are civil servants for who own regulations apply463. The share of salary due to private payments (payments from patients in private wards/beds) is not regulated in a uniform way. Normally these funds are distributed among the doctors and other health care personnel by means of a distribution key. They sometimes represent a considerable share of a physicians’ salary, especially for doctors higher up in the hierarchy (e.g. heads of departments). Physicians employed in hospitals are allowed to undertake part-time jobs, e.g. to open their own private practice. Restrictions may be related to regulations of public services law. Impact of the LKF System When introducing the performance orientated payment system for inpatient care in Austria, thus substituting the payment based on daily fees by performance orientated case based payments, the most important aims were to contain costs and to increase efficiency for inpatient-care.464 Studies discussing the impact of the LKF system have, amongst others, been undertaken by Leonard, Rauner, Schaffhauser-Linzatti and Yap465 (Impact of the reimbursement system on inpatient-admissions and discharges in Austrian and Canadian hospitals466), by Sommersguter-Reichmann and Stepan467 (Analysis of 462 Pfeiffer, K.P. (2001). What are the effects of case payments on hospital funding? presentation given 6 November 2001, accessed at http://www.imib.med.tu-dresden.de/imib/apis/tagu2001/KarlPeterPfeiffer.pdf on 04/05/2006 Pfeiffer, K.P. (2004). Performance-orientated hospital funding in Austria– Temporary conclusions and future perspectives. Presentation given in Seefeld. 463 Hofmarcher, M.M., Patterson, I., Riedel, M. (2002). ″Measuring Hospital Efficiency in Austria–A DEA approach.″ Health Care Management Science 5, pp. 7-14 464 ibid 465 Leonard, K.J., Rauner, M.S., Schaffhauser-Linzatti, M.M., Yap, R. (2003). ″The effect of funding policy on day of the week admissions and discharges in hospitals: the cases of Austria and Canada″, Health Policy 63, pp. 239-257 466 Databasis in Austria: inpatient data for all patients in LKF funded hospitals (85% of all inpatient cases in 1998) 467 Sommersguter-Reichmann, M./Stepan, A., Evaluating the New Activity-Based Hospital Financing System in Austria in: Dockner, E.J./Hartl, R.F./Luptacik, M./Sorger, G. Eds. (2000). Optimization, Dynamics and Economic Analysis. Physica, pp. 49-63. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 152 the impact of the LKF system on performance and costs) or by Hofmarcher, Lietz and Schnabl468 (DEA Analysis of the input-orientated efficiency of emergency units between 1997 and 2000). Hofmarcher, Lietz and Schnabl argue that the reduction in the increase in costs only had a short term effect. The increase in costs for hospitals in 2001 amounted to 3.8%, being higher than GDP growth and yearly inflation (1.6%).469 Sommersguter-Reichmann and Stepan show that the LKF System has led to point maximisation, especially in non-profit hospitals. Hospitals aim to enlarge their share of the budget. A reduction in the length of stay could not be clearly attributed to an early discharge of the patient or to a reduction of the excessive use of resources. Possibly inpatients were shifted to outpatient departments for follow-up care as outpatient cases have increased. Shifting of services, not only between inpatient wards and outpatient departments but also between hospitals and free-lance doctors practising outside of the hospital were observed. Especially the latter is problematic due to the fact that the two areas of health provision are based on different funding streams.470 In the DEA analysis performed by Hofmarcher et al. nearly all hospitals analysed in 1997 were efficient whilst only few hospitals were classified efficient in 1994-1996. The average efficiency score amounted to 90% in 1997 in comparison to 83% in 1996. The authors of the study assume that the increase in efficiency is mostly based on an increase of the technical efficiency, not the productive efficiency. As already mentioned before the introduction of the LKF system was followed by a decrease of the average length of stay in hospitals. However the number of inpatient-admissions has gone up constantly, this being partially rooted in the increase in day-clinic cases as well as case-splitting. Increases in costs were contained by capping expenditures. The Austrian association for health economics (Österreichische Gesellschaft für Gesundheitsökonomie, ÖGGÖ) 471 undertook a survey in 2004 researching the impact of the LKF system. The implications of the new system on costs, internal organization and planning, quality, services and other implications in hospitals were analysed. 600 experts in the field of hospitals care and in the health system were questioned out of which 110 replied, their answers were used for the evaluation. Roughly half of the questioned experts stated that the LKF system had contained the increase in costs, especially for the Federation and Social insurance (about 70% each), but also for hospitals (about 50%), the federal states and private health insurance funds (about 43% and 46% respectively). Actually the share for hospital funding of social insurance and the federation has increased more between 1996 and 2002 than the share of the regional funding entities. 84.6% said that no savings could be achieved. Experts stated that the LKF system has the following effects: - Extension of day clinics Reduction of acute beds Shifting of patients from ambulatory to inpatient care and vice versa Creation of 5-day wards 468 Hofmarcher, M.M., Lietz, C., Schnabl, A. (2005). ″Inefficiency in Austrian inpatient care: identifying ailing providers based on DEA results.″ Central European Journal of Operations Research, to be published 469 ibid 470 Sommersguter-Reichmann, M./Stepan, A., Evaluating the New Activity-Based Hospital Financing System in Austria in: Dockner, E.J./Hartl, R.F./Luptacik, M./Sorger, G. Eds. (2000). Optimization, Dynamics and Economic Analysis. Physica, pp. 49-63 471 Deszy, J., Holler, G., Spann, H., Schwarz, B. (2004). LKF funding, results of an expert survey by the Austrian Association of Health Economics 2003/2004. Presentation Deszy, J., Schwarz, B., Holler, G., Spann, H. (2004). ″Funding of the Austrian Health Care System.″ Gesundheitsoeconomica 2004, pp.5-79 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 153 With respect to multiple testing (duplication of diagnostic findings) 82% of the experts questioned believe that these were reduced. Nearly 88% linked the decline in average length of stay to the LKF system. Almost a quarter of the experts state that the LKF system has improved the quality of medical services, about 16% that it has improved nursing services and about 40% that it has led to a better quality of organizational services for patients (sum of the categories strongly improved and slightly improved). About 68% think that changes in quality are neutral. Close to three quarters of the experts believe that the system has led to early discharges and augmented re-admissions. Considering services as well as the data or costs, experts are of the opinion that the system has improved transparency in hospitals. With respect to shifting of services more than half of the experts state that shifts have taken place towards long-term-care. 45% declare that services have been shifted from one hospital to another or to extramural providers. Above 70% are neutral when asked to state if they think that the LKF System has improved communication between the different sectors in health care. About the same share believes that the system has not resulted in any reduced services for patients. Three quarters say that the LKF system may, in the short term (up to 2 years) or in the medium term (5-6 years), result in a reduction of beds. Around 85% of the experts questioned indicate that the LKF system does not encourage the referral of patients to the economically most suitable level of care. About half believe that the LKF system changes the structure of the health care system, roughly 85% that it distributes money. In the course of the survey the questioned experts were asked to list problems which have either not been solved or have been solved in an unsatisfactory way. The following examples were given: structural problems, lack of steering and planning, missing incentives (to encourage more economic behaviour), lack of quality assurance, problems related to interfaces. The following solutions were suggested: regional budgets, equal funding for equal services, centralised administration of funds. With regard to steering and planning, a stronger co-operation between intramural and extramural care ought to take place, furthermore transparency should be increased and supply planned better. When asked about their opinion on the most important targets of the health care agency, most of the experts quoted a fair reimbursement of services as well as interface management. Figure 6.6 Average length of stay in Austrian hospitals, 1995-2004 (without 0-day stays and long-term stays472) in hospitals funded by the federal health funds Source: BMGF (2006). Hospitals in figures, accessed at www. bmgf.gv.at on 07/06/2006473 Since the introduction of the LKF system a continuous decline in the average length of stay in hospitals has taken place. This is partially related to technological and medical advances, but also strongly influenced by the reimbursement mechanism employed, which does not entail any incentives to keep the patient in hospital longer than necessary. 472 Longer than 28 days Hospital Statistics (hospitals funded by the federal health funds (Landesfgesundheitsfonds), annual report (hospitals not funded by the federal health funds), reports on diagnosis and services (hospitals funded by the federal health funds) – average length of stay (all BMGF), Statistics Austria: Extrapolation of the population, yearly averages 1991–2004 (status: 23.05.2005) 473 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 154 Figure 6.7 Inpatient stays in Austrian 1991-2004 (1991 = 100) Inpatient stays 2004: hospitals funded by the federal health funds: 2,334,444/ hospitals not funded by the federal health funds: 253,542 Austria total, Hospitals funded by federal health funds (squares), hospitals not funded by federal hospital funds (circles) Source: BMGF (2006). Hospitals in figures accessed at www. bmgf.gv.at on 07/06/2006474 The number of inpatient stays has risen continuously since 1991, whereby the increase was stronger after the introduction of the LKF system, especially in hospitals not funded by the federal health funds. The collapse for hospitals not funded by the federal health funds in 1993/1994 originates in the fact that a hospital in Carinthia changed its status from pertaining to the hospitals not funded by the federal health funds to the hospitals funded by the federal health funds. The increase in 1-day cases has notably influenced the rise in inpatient stays. Also the day-clinic cases, which until 1996 were partially billed as outpatient cases and, since the introduction of the LKF system, have to be documented as inpatient stays. 6.4 Continuity of care Patients are increasingly seen by a variety of health care professionals in a wide variety of organizations and locations, raising concerns about fragmentation of care. On an international level, policy reports advocate a concerted effort to enhance continuity of care.475,476 However, there remains a lack of consensus on the definition of continuity and other related terms have been used, including continuum of care, coordination of care, discharge planning, case management, integration of services and seamless care.477 In primary care, continuity is mainly viewed as the relationship between a single practitioner and a patient that extends beyond specific episodes of illness or disease. Continuity implies a sense of affiliation between patients and their practitioners (my doctor or my patient), often expressed in terms of an implicit contract of loyalty by the patient and clinical responsibility by the provider.478 Explicit concern for continuity in 474 Data sources: Hospital Statistics (hospitals funded by the federal health funds), annual report (hospitals not funded by the federal health funds), reports on diagnosis and services (hospitals funded by the federal health funds) – average length of stay (all BMGF), Statistics Austria: Extrapolation of the population, yearly averages 1991–2004 (status: 23.05.2005) 475 World Health Organization, "The Ljubljana Charter on Reforming Health Care," (Geneva: World Health Organization, 1996). 476 N Fulop and P Allen, "National Listening Exercise: Report of the Findings," (London: NHS Service Delivery and Organization National Research and Development Program, 2000). 477 J.L Haggerty, R.J Reid, and G.K Freeman, "Continuity of Care: A Multidisciplinary Review," British Medical Journal 327 (2003). 478 I.R McWhinney, "Continuity of Care in Family Practice. Part 2: Implications of Continuity," Journal of Family Practice 2 (1975). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 155 medical specialties has emerged since the late 1980s, reflecting the increased complexity of managing long term diseases such as HIV and AIDS, diabetes, cardiovascular diseases, rheumatological conditions, and cancer. Continuity is seen as the delivery of services by different providers in a coherent, logical and timely fashion and is often referred to as a continuum of care. The specialty literature emphasises the content of care protocols or management strategies, with relatively little attention to the processes required for implementation.479 For continuity to exist, two distinguishing elements must be present - care of an individual patient and care delivered over time. For the first element, care of an individual patient, the unit of measurement of continuity is fundamentally the individual. Continuity is not an attribute of providers or organizations, but rather how individual patients experience integration of services and coordination. The second element, care over time, has been identified consistently as a longitudinal or chronological dimension of continuity.480 Continuity of care has many advantages, for instance: shorter consultations because of better prior knowledge of the patient and their history by the doctor, and generally more rational clinical decisions. Continuity of care is especially important for patients with co-morbidities or multi-morbidities. These patients have more that one illness, each of which may impact on the course and management of the others. The occurrence and degree of co-morbidity has been shown to increase with increasing age, lower level of education, and lower public health insurance.481 Therefore, addressing patients with co-morbidity is an important issue because it occurs disproportionately within populations that are socio-economically disadvantaged and in the elderly, and especially in for population that are both.482,483 The small percentage of the population with co-morbidities often makes up a disproportionate amount of the pharmaceutical consumption.484 From Austria, a study in Carinthia showed that 1.7% of patients contributed to one-quarter of expenditure, while 7% of patients made up 50% of expenditure. Also, 7% of patients contribute 26% of co-payments.485 These particularly expensive patients could be closely followed. Targeting could be directed towards less than 7% of the patients as some of these expensive patients may be in their final year of life, or may have received costly treatment following an accident. With no specific designation to a GP, these patients may seek therapy from different doctors who may be unaware of the other medicines they are taking and other conditions they may have. These patients may also receive care in a hospital setting, where more expensive therapies may be used. They will then likely request the same treatment when they return to a doctor of their choosing. Furthermore, a registry of such patients could be kept to identify people who could potentially be expensive for the health care system. Similar challenges exist in the treatment of patients with chronic conditions. The benefits of continuity may also be seen in prescribing costs - for instance, the lower costs of dispensing doctors who work in rural areas and who have greater continuity of care for their patients over urban doctors is in part attributed to stable care arrangements. The lack of continuity of care is a particular issue in urban areas where patients have wider choice of GP or of specialist. Patient choice is important; however, it is necessary for each patient to have a coordinating doctor to follow up with treatments, particularly for patients with multiple diseases. 479 H Campbell et al., "Integrated Care Pathways," British Medical Journal 316 (1998). J Rogers and P Curtis, "The Concept and Measurement of Continuity in Primary Care," American Journal of Public Health 70 (1980). 481 M van den Akker et al., "Multimorbidity in General Practice: Prevalence, Incidence, and Determinants of CoOccurring Chronic and Recurrent Diseases," Journal of Clinical Epidemiology 51 (1998). 482 A Menotti et al., "Prevalence of Morbidity and Multi-Morbidity in Elderly Male Populations and Their Impact on 10-Year All-Cause Mortality: The Fine Study (Finland, Italy, Netherlands, Elderly)," Journal of Clinical Epidemiology 45 (2001). 483 G Watt, "The Inverse Care Law Today," Lancet 360 (2002). 484 R Reid et al., "Conspicuous Consumption: Characterizing High Users of Physician Services in One Canadian Province," Journal of Health Services Research and Policy 8, no. 4 (2003). 485 Selbstbehalteanalyse (2002) anhand der Versicherungsleistungen der KGKK (von Direktor Mag. Alfred Wurzer, Mag. Roswitha Robinig, OE Revision, OE-L Josef Rodler, OE Organization). 480 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 156 6.4.1 Continuity of care in Austria The Austrian health care system is characterised by a big number of actors, who are involved in funding and/or providing health care services, the most important being Social Insurance, the federal states, the Federation, the local governments and private providers. Professional representations such as the Medical Chamber or the Chamber of Pharmacists have a very strong position in Austria. Responsibilities in funding and service provision were described in Chapter 3 of the report. Due to this fragmentation there is a considerable lack in continuity of care at all levels of the Austrian health care system as well as a lack in communication between the different levels. In Austria general practitioners only have very limited gatekeeping functions. Access to primary care physicians and other ambulatory health care institutions is more or less free, leaving patients a great deal of choice of providers. A referral note is only necessary for visiting a couple of medical specialities (e.g. physical medicine) or for performing special tests/investigations. However at some sickness funds a patient is only allowed to directly access a certain number of specialists per quarter (regulations vary at the different funds). Patients are entitled to use out-patient departments of hospitals or integrated providers (ambulatory clinics) of social insurance funds as first point of access when in need of care. Continuity of care and co-operation between ambulatory providers hardly takes place though the introduction of the e-card which was accompanied by an increased use of information technology incl. computers and the future introduction of the electronic health record may encourage and facilitate communication between providers. The lack in communication and coordination does not only refer to physicians amongst each other but also to the communication between the different health care professionals on the same level of care such as psychotherapists, physiotherapists, speech therapists, etc.. They are obliged to fulfil certain standards in terms of communication which however are not always met meaning that bilateral information (feedback) is sometimes lacking. Continuity of care between ambulatory and secondary care is hampered once again due to fragmentation of funding and responsibility. Social insurance pays for a great share of inpatient care but does hardly have any say in service provision. As social insurance mostly pays a lump sum payment for inpatient services provided for their insured population, hospitals try to shift patients outside of the hospital in order to save costs. Medicines (originators) are on occasion provided to hospitals free of charge by pharmaceutical companies, making it difficult for the ambulatory physician being visited by the patient after discharge, to explain why he has to change the medication given in hospital to a generic drug. Double testing and treatment does occur however doctors in hospitals are in the mean time apparently more willing to accept tests done by ambulatory providers and do not automatically decide to repeat them as soon as the patient arrives in hospital. Continuity of care following discharge of hospital, especially for patients who require more extensive care such as chronically ill patients is subject to considerable regional variations, no standardized procedures exist. Some health insurance funds employ so called “care coordinators” who are notified before the patient’s discharge and help the patient to prepare for the time after his inpatient stay (giving information on benefits of social health insurance, medication therapy, etc.). Health care provision in long-term care and for social services is strongly fragmented, making it difficult for people in need to get an overview over options available. Mostly private providers (social welfare organizations) provide services which are difficult to compare amongst each other and are characterised by regional variation. Also the provision of other services in health care, such as emergency services involves multiple actors making co-ordination extremely complicated. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 157 Hospital funding exists in 9 different regional variations. In addition a number of physician contracts (different sickness funds) exist; special arrangements apply to health care institutions. Instruments encouraging integrated care are for instance planning instruments such as the Structural Plan for Health Care (Österreichischer Strukturplan Gesundheit) incl. the plan for major equipment or the Location Plan which is negotiated between each regional Medical Chamber and the Hauptverband. Mechanisms to promote co-ordination and prevent shifting of resources are the agreement according to article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act, the co-ordination mechanism and sanctioning mechanism and the recently introduced Reformpool. Other measures facilitating communication are improved information technology infrastructure (e-card, electronic health record, etc.) and increased mobility of resources and patients. A range of projects to promote integrated care exist on various levels, either organised by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women (PIK – patient-orientated integrated treatment (Patientenorientierte Integrierte Krankenbetreuung486)), by social insurance funds (discharge co-ordinators, disease management programs, development of treatment pathways) by the federal states or by others. The regional sickness fund of Vienna has recently become the competence centre for integrated care, emphasising the need of activities in this field. 486 For further information visit the project’s website at http://www.univie.ac.at/pik/ LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 158 7. QUALITY OF CARE There is little evidence available comparing quality of care across countries, due to difficulties in defining and measuring quality, and collecting quality indicators in an accurate and systematic way. One survey on perceived quality of care suggests that there is some variability in perceived quality of health care and social services across the EU, with highest levels reported in Austria (Table 7.1).487 Table 7.1 Perceived quality of public services Quality of health service Austria 8.1 Belgium 7.6 France 7.1 Germany 6.5 Hungary 5.3 Ireland 5.3 Italy 5.8 Poland 4.7 the Netherlands 6.7 United Kingdom 6.4 6.4 EU 15 5.0 10 New Member States Quality of social service 7.6 7.1 6.4 6.7 4.8 6.1 5.7 4.0 6.7 5.8 6.2 4.5 Question 54: In general, how would you rate the quality of each of the public services in [country]? Please tell me on a scale of one to 10, where one means very poor quality and 10 means very high quality – health services, social services. Source: Anderson 2004 7.1 Appropriateness of care Appropriateness of care is a relatively new area of concern in health care, with only a small number of initiatives, and even fewer that have been evaluated. This section outlines these initiatives, identifies the role of pharmacies in achieving appropriate pharmaceutical care, raises the important of regulating medical errors and highlights some of the concerns associated with dental care. There are many strategies that are used in Europe to ensure appropriateness of medical care. These strategies broadly consist of quality assurance, health technology assessment, systematic reviews, clinical guidelines, and monitoring providers’ performance. The Cochrane Collaboration which is based in the UK prepares and maintains systematic reviews of available medical evidence with which other European countries can participate in. Regulating prescribing patterns is another method used to ensure a suitable level of appropriateness of care. Prescribing patterns differ significantly across countries. For instance, only 62.9% of consultations result in prescriptions in the Netherlands, compared to 94.5% in Italy. Various approaches have been made to monitor prescribing quality, such as the use of a Medical Appropriateness Index which assesses prescribing suitability.488 In the UK, prescribing data are used to provide doctors with reliable and regular information on their current prescribing in an attempt to encourage more effective and economical prescribing. 487 R. Anderson, "Health and Health Care," in Quality of Life in Europe. First European Quality of Life Survey 2003, ed. European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 2004). 488 E Mossialos, M Mrazek, and T Walley, "Regulating Pharmaceuticals in Europe: An Overview," in Regulating Pharmaceuticals in Europe, ed. E Mossialos, M Mrazek, and T Walley (Maidenhead: Open University Press, 2004). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 159 Clinical practice guidelines – specific criteria for how and when particular tests and treatments should be used – may also reduce disparities in treatment across physicians as well as control spending.489 While it is difficult to monitor and enforce these guidelines, financial incentives (or disincentives) coupled with educational efforts may improve compliance. In France, there has been poor compliance with prescribing guidelines for many reasons: the volume of guidelines, lack of information systems and limited capacity for monitoring, and physicians concern that following the guidelines could negatively affect the quality of care being delivered.490 The effectiveness of clinical guidelines is uncertain.491 While some studies demonstrate minimal effect of clinical guidelines on physician prescribing behaviour492, others suggest that well-designed and consistently implemented guidelines can help to deliver “best practice”.493 While most guidelines seek to improve quality of care, others are designed with the explicit objective of cost-containment. The latter, however, are unlikely to be acceptable because of ethical and legal implications.494 Also, if clinical guidelines are not legislated, as in Finland, they may not be as successful in improving quality of care. Variation in medical treatment creates a need for improved quality control. In response to wide discrepancies in operative procedures across different hospitals in Belgium, a recent Advisory Commission of experts highlighted the need for benchmarking and quality control. However, these proposals have been met with considerable resistance from the providers. A National Guidelines Project was recently launched in Italy, which outlines evidence-based guidelines in order to reduce medical practice variation for certain conditions, however the specification of the conditions that are include have been left to the individual regions. At present, there are no policies in Germany that provide guidance or attempt to control medical errors, despite it being a widely recognized problem. Pharmacies play a role in ensuring appropriateness of pharmaceutical care. Hospital pharmacies’ functions have transformed since the 1970s. The role of hospital pharmacists has expanded to include working as clinical pharmacists at the ward level along with their traditional responsibilities of drug preparation and verification. Hospital pharmacies increasingly provide products to meet individual patient need, thus necessitating increased collaboration between hospital pharmacists and prescribers, nurses, dieticians, biochemists, and laboratory scientist. On an institutional level, hospital pharmacies must support the safe, effective, and economic use of medicines in hospitals in accordance with government rules and budgetary requirements. Thus, medical information and clinical pharmacy services are needed in the hospital to service outpatient care. In addition, specialised databases and medicine information services based in hospitals have been developed to facilitate drug treatment decision-making by clinicians.495 489 T Walley and E Mossialos, "Financial Incentives and Prescribing," in Regulating Pharmaceuticals in Europe, ed. E Mossialos, M Mrazek, and T Walley (Maidenhead: Open University Press, 2004). 490 P Durieux et al., "From Clinical Recommendations to Mandatory Practice," International Journal of Technology Assessment in Health Care 16, no. 4 (2000). 491 L. Gundersen, "The Effect of Clinical Practice Guidelines on Variations in Care," Annals of Internal Medicine 133 (2000). 492 I Hetlevik et al., "Implementing Clinical Guidelines in the Treatment of Diabetes Mellitus in General Practice," International Journal of Technology Assessment in Health Care 16 (2000). 493 F.B Garfield and J.M. Garfield, "Clinical Judgment and Clinical Practice Guidelines," International Journal of Technology Assessment in Health Care 16, no. 4 (2000), M Perleth, E Jakubowski, and R. Busse, "What Is 'Best Practice' in Health Care? State of the Art and Perspectives in Improving the Effectiveness and Efficiency of the European Health Care Systems," Health Policy 56, no. 3 (2001), R Richman and D.R. Lancaster, "The Clinical Guideline Process within a Managed Care Organization.," International Journal of Technology Assessment in Health Care 16, no. 4 (2000). 494 A.O Carter et al., "Proceedings of the 1994 Canadian Clinical Practice Guidelines Network Workshop," Canadian Medical Association Journal 153 (1995), T.S. Cheah, "The Impact of Clinical Guidelines and Clinical Pathways on Medical Practice: Effectiveness and Medico-Legal Aspects," Annals of the Academy of Medicine, Singapore 27, no. 4 (1998). 495 N Taggiasco, B Sarrut, and C.G Doreau, "European Survey of Independent Drug Information Centres,," Annals of Pharmacotherapy 26 (1992). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 160 7.1.1 Quality of care in Austria During the past years not only the notion of quality but also the awareness that more ought to be done for this topic has received increasing attention in Austria.496 Developments are briefly discussed in the following section. In the 1993 amendment of the Hospital Act for the first time country wide measures for quality assurance were defined in the form of the mandatory establishment of commissions for quality assurance in hospitals. Moreover patient rights and hospital hygienists were mentioned for the first time. In the agreement according to article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act, valid for 1997 to 2000, quality is for the first time defined as a duty of the structural commission (Strukturkommission), in the agreement of 2001 to 2004 quality is incorporated into an own article and country wide quality projects are initiated by the Federation. The starting point for the Quality in Health Care Act, which came into effect on January 1 2005 were about 50 nation wide quality-related regulations as well as 20 projects of the resort on quality in terms of structures, processes and outcomes. The Quality in Health Care Act represents an embracing of all hitherto existing quality regulations which are distributed across a range of laws. Provisions not only apply over the whole of Austria but span all professions and sectors (coverage of all actors in the health system). The aim was to establish a nation wide quality system which should have regard to the aspects of patient orientation, transparency, effectiveness and efficiency as well as patient safety. The Quality in Health Care Act gives the Federal Minister of Health the possibility to enact decrees related to various topics, amongst others on quality reporting, optimisation of the use of antibiotics, assessment of patient satisfaction, patient safety, disease management/case management programs, interface management497. Actual implementation of these is dependent on a range of factors, among other things on the political willpower and courage of decision makers. Quality is defined in the Quality in Health Care Act (Gesundheitsqualitätsgesetz), in § 2 para.2 as “Degree of fulfilment of the attributes of patient-orientated, transparent and efficient provision of health care services”. “At the centre of concern are, in this context, the optimisation of quality in terms of structures, processes and outcomes”.498 “When providing the services patient safety has to be taken into consideration”.499 Furthermore, in the elucidations of the law, quality is stated to be “ the relation between a (defined) ideal state and the actual realisation of a service, being either a product, a service, a process or a system” 500 In the Quality in Health Care Act addition definitions, e.g. structural quality, process quality and outcome quality are provided in § 2. The Law envisages the implementation of a quality-strategy/ a quality system for the whole of Austria for all professions for all sectors by which quality requirements for the provision of health care services are dictated on a mandatory basis. - - Quality reporting In the course of the negotiations related to the article 15a of the Austrian Constitutional Act on the restructuring of the health system and hospital funding, valid through 2001-2004, the Structural Commission (Strukturkommission) was given the responsibility of initiating a country wide system of quality reporting.501 A project, with the following aims, was started.502 496 Dr. Fronaschütz (Federal Ministry of Health and Women, BMGF). Interview 21 December 2005 Fronaschütz, U. (2005). Information Session 2: Quality in Health Care Act. Presentation given 17 January 2005 (Health Care Conference) 498 Quality in Health Care Act 499 Elucidations Quality in Health Care Act 500 Elucidations Quality in Health Care Act 501 Quality reporting in health care. Accessed at www.qbe.at on 12/07/2006 502 Quality reporting in health care. Accessed at www.qbe.at on 12/07/2006 497 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 161 - - Development of an Austrian system of quality reporting as well as setting up a quality report entailing a comprehensive description of activities related to quality in the Austrian health care system The quality report should be flexible and subject to continuous further development Definition of a country wide implementation strategy for the yearly quality reporting system. Compulsory and systematic discussion and inclusion of all relevant actors, organizations and carriers in the quality reporting process Using the Austrian quality reporting as basis for comprehensive planning in the health care system For the first time it was debated to establish a database for quality projects as well as a database for quality related strategies in hospitals. Both were realized in the form of pilot projects. The results and the final report on quality reporting and the pilot projects were handed over to the ministry but have, until now, not been published. Quality reporting is regulated in § 6 of the Quality in Health care Act (Gesundheitsqualitätsgesetz), see Appendix 9. The Austrian Social Insurance for Occupational risks (Allgemeine Unfallversicherungsanstalt, AUVA) has been publishing a quality report on quality management in accident hospitals and rehabilitation centres since 1996503. The report can be accessed and downloaded at/from the AUVA’s504 website. The quality management system of the AUVA is based on the method of the PDCA (plan-do-check-act) cycle whereby a detailed system of quality assurance was developed underlying continuous further development. During the past years 40 mandatory quality standards were agreed on. The quality assurance system encompasses continuing training and education of staff (in the fields of quality management, evidence based medicine and project management), development of guidelines and clinical pathways, periodical evaluation of the quality standards, patient safety and risk management, furthermore certification. In addition a range of quality-related activities take place in order to make quality work more accessible for parties involved and interested. The cooperative management (kollegiale Führung) demonstrates significant involvement in quality work. The Vienna association of hospitals (Wiener Krankenanstaltenverbund) also publishes a quality report. The focus of their quality work is on the fields of patient- and staff orientation, process- and resource orientation as well as organization505. In the report a range of initiatives, projects and activities of their quality work can be found. For each hospital a list is made based on the following criteria: title of the initiative/project/activity, contact person, duration, focus, aims and result. Several hospitals publish quality reports, such as the hospitals of the Vinzenz-Group506, for instance the Krankenhaus der barmherzigen Schwestern in Linz507 or in Ried508 or the state hospital (Landeskrankenhaus) Stolzalpe.509 In addition to these there are health care institutions or individual departments of health care institutions which have taken part in certifications or accreditation processes, like as for example the state hospital Villach which is accredited by Joint Commission or numerous laboratories which are certified according to ISO 9000ff. 503 Austrian Social Insurance for Occupational Risks, AUVA. Information provided on the telephone 13/07/2006 Austrian Social Insurance for Occupational Risks , accessed at www.auva.at 505 Quality report of the Vienna association of hospitals 2003. accessed at http://www.wienkav.at/_cache/Doku/big/KAV%20Qualitätsbericht%202003_5848.pdf on 12/07/2006 506 See Website of the hospitals of the Vinzenz group, accessed at www.vinzenzgruppe.at 507 Quality report 2003/2004. accessed at http://www.bhs.at/linz/index.asp?peco=&Seite=435&Lg=1&Cy=1&UID on 12/07/2006 508 Quality report (2005). accessed at http://www.bhs.at/ried/redsyspix/download/Qualitaetsbericht%20final%20an%20KTQ.pdf on 12/07/2006 509 Quality report 2005. Accessed at http://www.lkh-stolzalpe.at/cms/dokumente/10011283_2248709/fc780f97/QMJahresbericht_2005_freigegebene%20Version.pdf on 12/07/2006 504 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 162 The hospitals of the federal state of Lower Austria (Landeskliniken) have decided to implement a uniform system for quality management. Furthermore an assessment of the structure and the organization of quality assurance in the individual state hospitals were performed.510 National programs to improve quality of care In the course of the last agreement according to article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act the Federal Ministry of Health and Women supported and funded 5 major projects related to the topic of quality:511 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. Quality reporting Pat – Patient orientation in hospitals MedTogether – Management of interfaces Strategy for antibiotics Optimisation of the use of blood All of these projects have already been finished. Within the framework of quality reporting the setup of a database for quality projects was initiated by the BMGF. In the same context a pilot project on quality strategies in hospitals was performed. The results of the pilot projects have been passed on to the ministry but have so far not been published. Austrian Structure Plan for Health Care (Österreichischer Strukturplan Gesundheit, ÖSG) The Austrian Structure Plan for health care replaced the formerly existing hospital plan and plan for major equipment (Krankenanstalten- und Großgeräteplan) on January 1st 2006. The plan constitutes, according to the agreement based on article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act, a compulsory basis for the integrated planning of the Austrian health care structure and is applicable to all sectors. Mandatory quality standards for planning are an integrated part of the plan. At the moment these exist for acute inpatient care. Those for non-acute inpatient care, for ambulatory care, rehabilitation and interfaces to long-term care will be defined continuously and will become part of the ÖSG. Social insurance quality projects512 Also in social insurance the topic of “quality“ has received increasing attention in the past. This is not only visible in the definition of goals and priorities in the course of the Balanced Scorecard process but also in the rising number of projects in this area. In 2003 and 2004 the project “Framework Quality Assurance” was performed by the Hauptverband which was accompanied by an exhaustive collection of quality-related regulations and norms as well as provisions in the Hauptverband and at the health insurance funds. In the course of the definition of socalled Standard Products (Standardprodukte)513 of Social Insurance the project “Quality in health care”, consisting of nine sub-projects, was started in 2004.514 Some of the sub-projects have been completed in the mean time. Following the titles of all sub-projects: - Codesystem ambulatory care Software support of the quality work in physician’ practices Metamodel Quality Implementation of a drug utilization review Health care information systems for patients Hospital organization of the future (concept of the competence centre Hanusch-Krankenhaus) Austrian Drug Reimbursement Knowledge Management Quality 510 Niederösterreichischer Landesrechnungshof St. Pölten (2005). Quality assurance in hospitals 2/2005 accessed at http://www.noe.gv.at/service/politik/landtag/LandtagsvorlagenXVI/04/492/38B.pdf on 12/07/2006 511 Dr. Fronaschütz (Federal Ministry of Health and Women, BMGF). Interview 21 December 2005 512 Projects of or initiated by the Hauptverband 513 formerly known as „Innovation Projects“(products/solutions developed for use of all insurance funds) 514 Mag. Lichtenecker (Insurance fund of the Austrian Railway and Mining Industry, VAEB). New design and new start. The projects were initiated step by step. Information provided via email 20/07/2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 163 The project “Metamodel Quality” braces the individual sub-projects and is supposed to display their quality aspects in a total system view. The aim of the project was to develop an integrated quality model which should be the basis for decisions on resources. It was orientated towards the WHO 21 Health for All Targets (HfA21) for the European region. The Patient view is put at the centre, health economics is interpreted as subject of quality management through which an integrated quality model is made possible. More detailed information on the project (Executive summary) can be found in the Appendix 10. Further projects of all health insurance funds include for instance the definition of minimum opening hours for physician practices, optimising waiting times, securing barrier free access to physician practices, improving the quality of the PAP-smears at gynecologists – QUOPAP (quality push PAP-smear), the improvement of quality in the field of clinical, psychological diagnostics as well as the labeling of quality regulations. The overall goal is to guarantee good quality for the insured and to put more weight on the role of consumer protection. Health insurance funds were, in the course of a survey performed in November 2005, asked to state the quality projects of their fund. Responses were as follows (see Appendix 11 for details): Completed projects: barrier free access for all contract partners, extension of minimum opening hours of practices, implementation of treatment recommendations for hypertension (regional sickness fund of Burgenland, BGKK), publications in the course of the pharmaceutical dialog (regional sickness fund of Upper Austria, OOEGKK), DIALA Case Management (OOEGKK), PAP smear (regional sickness fund of Carinthia, KGKK), standardized and anonymous enquiry- and authorization process for psychotherapy (regional sickness fund of Salzburg, SGKK), treatment guidelines for social insurance institutions (integrated providers) (SGKK, adopted from the OOEGKK), quality- and environment management system following the regulations of DIN EN ISO 9902 and DIN EN ISO 14001 (ISO-certification) in integrated health care institutions (regional sickness fund of Vorarlberg, VGKK). Projects in process: improving the quality of prescribing, increased prescribing of generics, efficiency project/ DEA to ensure treatment quality (regional sickness fund of Vienna, WGKK), AMI (myocardial infarction), EPOETIN for anemia (BGKK), Disease Management, Diabetes consultation, treatment at home (regional sickness fund of Styria, STGKK), IVSOOE (stroke project) (OOEGKK), improvement of the quality of PAP-smears (OOEGKK), physical medicine (SGKK), quality assurance for expert opinion related to long term care (Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business, SVA). Continuous projects/activities: enforcing the inclusion of quality standards in the reimbursement list/fee structure (training, equipment, documentation, etc.). Planned projects: Participation in the OEBIG515 Project “implementation of a quality assured mammography screening program in Austria (OOEGKK), development of standards for digital imaging and electronic archiving in radiology (regional sickness fund of Lower Austria, NOEGKK). In addition increased activities related to the development of guidelines and clinical pathways should be undertaken. Nationwide funds (BVA, SVA, VAEB) take part in some of the projects initiated by the regional sickness funds. DEA project of the regional sickness fund of Vienna516 The aim of the project performed in 2005 was to ensure the efficiency and quality of medical treatment. Efficiency of physicians in practices was calculated by means of the instrument of Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA). Inputs were fees, expenses for pharmaceuticals and referral-costs. Data from the first quarter in 2004 were used for the measurement of efficiency. Potential for improvement was assessed in such a way that physicians with an efficiency score of less than 73% were stated to be inefficient. These physicians were attended personally by explaining them how the score was calculated and from which inputs it results. The focus of the conversations held by doctors was: laboratories, radiology (MRT, CT 515 516 Austrian Federal Institute for Health Care (ÖBIG) Dr. Eger (Regional sickness fund of Vienna, WGKK). Interview 26 January 2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 164 examinations), pharmaceuticals. The project was completed on December 31st, in total 200 GPs and specialists were analysed. In the future contact to contract partners should be enforced to ensure sustainability, the number of physicians will be raised. The project should become part of the standard procedures in the regional sickness fund of Vienna. For further details on the project, see Appendix 12. Quality of care and physicians Activities related to quality on the level of physicians are on the one hand defined by legislation (e.g. documentation, training, quality assurance for physicians in ambulatory care) and on the other hand based on activities of the medical associations (for the various medical specialties), the professional organizations (Austrian Medical Chamber and the Chambers in the federal states, Austrian Chamber of Dentists) or other institutions (e.g. hospitals). Examples are for instance in terms of legislation the evaluation of primary care physicians in their practices according to § 118a Physician Act (devolved to the ÖQMed Association), in terms of the medical associations the development of guidelines and quality indicators and in terms of the professional organizations the provision of continuing professional education of physicians (devolved to the Austrian Academy of Physicians), the development of a guideline for quality assurance and the organization of quality circles. Further projects for quality assurance are the ANISS project (Austrian Nosocomial Infection Surveillance System – a HELICS pilot project), the QIP project (Quality Indicator Project), a project which originates in the United States whereby hospitals engage in a benchmarking process, based on self assessed indicators. In Austria about 35-40 hospitals take part in this project, mainly situated in Upper Austria (the national coordination office is funded by the BMGF and is placed in Linz, contact: Ms. Reli Mechtler). Beyond the above mentioned projects there is a project to improve palliative care, in which the focus is put on the training of parties involved. In the context of the project a curriculum for care is developed, that for doctors is currently being produced. A project on hospital hygiene which is currently being revised i.e. newly designed it PROHYG. In a first step (performed the first time in 2002) indicators were collected and guidelines developed (PROHYG guidelines) which were subsequently tested. Now the situation should be evaluated and the guidelines updated.517 A disease related project is the founding of a network for stroke as well as the setting-up of a stroke register for joint documentation of the stroke units in Austria. The aim is to exchange experiences and develop standards.518 An overview over a couple of quality projects (accessible to the public) can be found on the website of the forumQ. (Information centre for quality management in health care at the Karl Landsteiner Institute for hospital organization) at www.forumQ.at. Quality projects for preventive services and for services in the field of health promotion are performed by the Healthy Austria Fund (Fonds Gesundes Österreich) .519 Examples are for instance the projects health promoting hospitals, health promoting schools.520 Targets to improve quality The responsibility for the development of national quality standards, applicable to all professions and sectors was transferred to the Federal Institute for Quality in Health Care. This is about to be founded and should be joined together with the Health Care Austria Plc. (Gesundheit Österreich GmbH). 517 Dr. Arrouas (Federal Ministry of Health and Women, BMGF). Interview 13 January 2006 Lang, W., Lalouschek, W. (2002). ″A network against stroke, report on the second Vienna stroke day - on the occasion of the world stroke day. Journal für Neurologie, Neurochirurgie und Psychiatrie 3 (2), pp. 48-52 519 Which will be merged with the Austrian Institute for Quality in Health Care and the Austrian Federal Institute for Health Care to become the Health Care Austria Plc. 520 Dr. Geyer (Federal Ministry of Health and Women, BMGF). Interview 29 December 2005 518 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 165 In addition, as already mentioned, a range of legal provisions on quality assurance exist, amongst others in the Physician Act, in the Medicine products Act or in the General Social Insurance Act. The majority of health insurance funds states that they have defined quality targets solely for the provision of medical services- The following targets were quoted when responding to the survey among the health insurance funds, performed in November 2005 (for details see Appendix 13). Quality targets in the fee structure: proof of training for certain equipment, proof of training/education, period for keeping medical records, own targets in laboratory medicine, provisions for the laboratory catalogue 2005, -for the pathology catalogue 2005. Targets in the General contract: disability free access for new contract partners, quality indicators for allergy ambulatories, for contract institutes for physical medicine (spas) and quality standards in new contracts. Other targets: Durability of fillings from dentists, care for MS patients: checking on the scope of diagnostics before diagnosis by the medical officer at the sickness fund for all processes of care: orientation following procedure instructions in dental ambulatory clinics, periodical and successful participation in interlaboratory comparisons. National monitoring of quality programs The Quality in Health Care Act (Gesundheitsqualitätsgesetz, GQG) created the legal basis to dictate quality standards to all health care institutions and to assess their compliance with them521. The GQG became effective on January 1, 2005. In the law the establishment of a federal institute for quality in health care is envisaged which will amongst other duties be responsible for developing incentive mechanisms and external controls. The actual implementation of the law (in form of ordinances) will still take a while. Also before the creation of the above mentioned law measures to ensure and assess the quality of care provided existed. In the area of inpatient care, for instance the Austrian hospital and major equipment plan existed until December 31, 2005 and was replaced by the Austrian Structural Plan for health care thereafter. The regulations of the structural plan like for example the quality standards related to the structure of health care institutions (for staffing, infrastructural requirements, medically or scientifically stipulated minimum frequencies) are mandatory. Individual structural plans were developed in all federal states. Legal provisions related to quality assessment are amongst others in the Hospital Act (Krankenanstalten und Kuranstalten Gesetz), in the Medical Devices Act (Medizinproduktegesetz) and in the General Social Insurance Act (Allgemeines Sozialversicherungsgesetz). Beyond these there are international provisions for quality assurance which have to be followed.522 Sanitary supervision of health care institutions is part of the responsibility of public health physicians. Federal Institute for Quality in Health Care According to § 9 para.1 of the Quality in Health Care Act a Federal Institute for Quality in Health Care will be established. It will support the Federal Minister of Health and Women in conducting and realising his/her assigned duties. The institute has the following responsibilities, taking into consideration a country-wide approach spanning all sectors and professions as well as the principles of patient orientation, transparency, effectiveness and efficiency. Furthermore international standards (see also Appendix 14): 1. „Cooperation in the development of general guidelines and principles a) for the definition of standards in the fields of quality in terms of structures, processes and outcomes b) for documentation related to quality reporting and for quality reporting itself c) for motivating- and incentive mechanisms 521 Dr. Arrouas (Federal Ministry of Health and Women, BMGF). Interview 13 January 2006 Fronaschütz, U. (2005). Information Session 2: Quality in Health Care Act. Presentation given 17 January 2005 (Health Care Conference) “ 522 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 166 d) for control according to § 8 para.1 2. Inspection-, recommendation- and development of quality standards which can be enacted by the Federal Minister of Health and Women (federal rules for quality (Bundesqualitätsrichtlinien) or recommended as guide for orientation (federal guidelines, Bundesleitlinie). 3. Development of a yearly quality report 4. Execution of i.e. cooperation in posing motivation- and incentive mechanisms 5. Enforcement of i.e. cooperation in the supervision of the compliance with provisions of this law as well as with decrees enacted in the course of this law or any other specifications. 6. Support of the Federal Minister of Health and Women in coordinating country wide measures for quality in order to ensure national and international comparability of health care services“ The institute does not yet exist, it is about to be established. On April 20, 2006 the Council of Ministers decided on the merging of the Healthy Austria Fund (Fonds Gesundes Österreich), the Austrian Federal Institute for Health Care (Österreichischen Bundesinstitutes für Gesundheitswesen, ÖBIG) to the “Healthcare Austria Plc.” (Gesundheit Austria GmbH). The Federal Institute for Quality in Health Care will also be integrated into the company. The decision of parliament was heavily criticized by the opposition. The future “Health Care Austria Plc” will be owned to 100% by the Federation. The 1993 amendment to the Hospital Act dictated the establishment of commissions for quality assurance in hospitals. In the context of quality reporting a pilot project was initiated in which a database collecting quality strategies of hospitals was set up. The results of this pilot project are in the ministry and have not yet been published. Quality control in ambulatory care takes place by means of voluntary as well as, only recently introduced, mandatory measures. Voluntary measures are for instance processes of certification (ISO), -of accreditation (EFQM, Joint Commission), quality circles and peer reviews. With the fifth amendment of the Physician Act a compulsory quality control was introduced. It is organised as a self-assessment whereby physicians assess the quality of their practices by answering a questionnaire (60 questions). The quality indicators in the questionnaire were defined by the physicians in co-operation with a scientific board of experts. For the time being it only includes criteria belonging to the dimensions of structure or process quality. The responses are checked for plausibility, in addition random inspections of practices take place. By 2008 about 15,000 practices will be evaluated, which are then re-assessed every two to three years523. Evaluations started mid April 2006:524 The responsibility for the quality assessment, according to § 118a Physician Act, lies with the Quality assurance association ÖQMed which was founded especially for this reason and is owned to 100% by the Physicians.525 Not only is it the association’s duty to come up with quality indicators but also to administer a quality register as well as performing quality controls. Quality defects are to be corrected within a certain time span, otherwise the physician takes the risk receiving a disciplinary complaint with the Chamber of Physicians. Health insurance funds are entitled to take a look at the evaluation results of their contract partners.526 523 HÖ (2005). ″ Quality in physician practices.″ Medical Tribune 18, accessed at http://www.medicaltribune.at/dynasite.cfm?dssid=4170&dsmid=63806&dspaid=484448 on November 18th 2005 524 Austrian Medical Chamber (2006). PK „Quality assurance in Austrian physician practices“, dated 15 March 2006, accessed at: http://www.aek.or.at/cache/000000000020060315112322.xml/PK-Unterlage%202006-0315.pdf, on 11/04/2006 525 Wirtschaftsblatt 9.11.05. Health care – argument about quality control in practices escalates – Ministry urges for solution, physicians do not want to be controlled. 526 Czypionka, T., Riedel, M., Röhrling, G. (2006). ″Europe in motion: Quality of care in physicians’ practices.″ Health System Watch I, supplement of the journal of Austrian social insurance, Soziale Sicherheit LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 167 In addition to the before mentioned compulsory standards there are non-binding quality standards in form of guidelines which are for instance developed by the respective medical associations or social insurance. Furthermore recommendations, issued by the Ministry of Health and Women (Strategy for the use of antibiotics, ProHyg guidelines). Monitoring of quality projects is effected by use of the strategic instrument Balanced Scorecard and other mechanisms for project management. In addition measures for quality control in integrated health care institutions exists as well as for contract partners. Controls of contract partners are usually ex-post controls to check compliance with quality provisions in the fee structure as well as reactions to patient complaints. In the course of the health insurance fund survey performed in November 2005 nearly all sickness funds replied that they perform quality controls not only for their integrated health care institutions but also for their contract physicians. Examples for quality controls in integrated health care institutions are commissions for quality assurance, operating approvals, ISO certifications and external quality assessments. Examples for quality controls of contract physicians are: proof of participation in quality circles, participation in interlaboratory comparisons, examination of training and equipment requirements, patient surveys and appraisals. Detailed responses of the health insurance funds, see Appendix 15. A considerable problem is the fact that social insurance only disposes of few possibilities to actually measure the quality of the services provided, another that it does not have appropriate instruments to sanction, only in the case of fraud, severe treatment errors or the suspicion of abuse. 7.2 Patient safety and medical errors Medical errors present a significant, although largely preventable barrier to high quality health care. Thus, policy makers, medical professional and patients are conferring an increasing amount of attention to the occurrence of and risks attached to medical errors. Medical errors result in 44,000-98,000 unnecessary deaths and over one million injuries per year in the US 527 and about 18,000 unnecessary deaths per year in Australia in addition to 50,000 patients becoming disabled528. A follow on study from Wilson et al.’s work on quality in Australian health care found that of any potential cause, human error accounted for the most adverse events (81.8%). This result highlights the need for systems to be put in place that limit the contact patients have with the unavoidable occurrence of human errors. In the US, fatalities from prescription errors were found to have increased by 243 per cent from 1993 to 1998, outpacing almost any other cause of death, and also progressing faster than the increase in prescriptions.529 Also errors in prescribing medications appeared to be the most common mistake made among family physicians.530 Another study in an American teaching hospital reports finding four errors per 1,000 medication orders, 70 per cent of which had the potential to be seriously harmful.531 Preventable adverse reactions to drugs are claimed to be the single leading cause of hospitalisation in the US, where 2 per cent to 7 per cent of hospitalised patients have avoidable adverse drug events and consequently have 527 American Hospital Association, "Hospital Statistics," (Chicago: 1999). R.M. Wilson et al., "The Quality in Australian Health Care Study," Medical Journal of Australia 163 (1995). 529 D.P. Phillips and C.C. Bredder, "Morbidity and Mortality from Medical Errors: An Increasingly Serious Public Health Problem," Annual Review of Public Health 23 (2002). 530 S.M Dovey et al., "Types of Medical Errors Commonly Reported by Family Physicians.," American Family Physician 67, no. 4 (2003). 531 Timothy S. Lesar, L. Briceland, and D.S. Stein, "Factors Related to Errors in Medication Prescribing," Journal of the American Medical Association 277, no. 4 (1997). 528 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 168 hospitals stays 8 to 12 days longer than they should.532 Studies done in the UK have shown similar results, with one report of a 49 per cent error rate in the administration of intravenous drugs.533 Medical errors have been attributed to a number of causes: administrative and investigation failures, simple ignorance, lapses in treatment delivery, miscommunication, complications in payment systems, among many others.534 Others suggest that medical errors arise from poor design of health care delivery processes as opposed to technical incompetence among health care professionals.535 Patients who face multiple interventions and have more serious conditions causing them to remain in hospital longer are more likely to suffer consequences resulting from a medical error. Otherwise, all patients regardless of sex, age and level of comorbidities face medical error risks.536 Without robust information systems to track medical error occurrences and difficulties in documenting their occurrence such as universal underreporting, assessing the actual size of medical errors as a problem remains difficult.. Not only do adverse events represent a concern for patient safety but also to health care system finances as they lead to greater medical complications or even patient deaths. A Harvard study of adverse drug events found that such events led to an increase length of stay by 2.2 days while preventable adverse drug events led to an increase of 4.6 days.537 Bates el al. also found that adverse drug events cost a 700 bed teaching hospital over GBP 3.5million per year. In addition, errors lead to intangible costs such as diminished trust in health systems, medical professionals and individual hospitals and physical and psychological effects of prolonged hospital stays and/or disability levels.538 The first systematic research on medical errors throughout Europe was released in January 2006 with a Eurobarometer survey assessing citizens’ perceptions of medical errors throughout the European Union (EU)539. This fills in some of the gaps in the medical errors literature as the majority of work on the topic comes from the US and to a lesser extent Australia. The Eurobarometer survey included all EU-25 states as well as the accession (Bulgaria and Romania) and candidate countries (Croatia and Turkey). Findings illustrate a wide variety across Europe in risk perceptions associated with and experiences pertaining to medical errors. This survey found that 78% of EU citizens found medical errors to be an important problem in their country, however country-level data found wide differences ranging from 97% in Italy to 48% in Finland. 63% of Austrians saw medical errors as an important problem in their country currently, putting it below the EU-25 average. However, when asked if they are worried about suffering a serious medical error, Austrians were the least worried in the EU-25 apart from Swedes and Dutch respondents with 76% expressing no concerns. Women, age and lower education levels tend to be associated with a higher likelihood of perceiving medical errors as an important problem. Clearly, those who have actually experienced a medical error or who have had a family member in such a situation tend to be more likely to view the problem as important and to be more prone to worrying about suffering a medical error. Austrians expressed particular assurance regarding quality in hospital care in responses collected as part of the Eurobarometer survey. As the figure demonstrates below, Austrians appear to be confident about experiences in hospitals relative to the rest of the EU-25. 532 L.T. Kohn, J.M. Corrigan, and M.S. Donaldson, eds., To Err Is Human: Building a Safer Health System, Committee on Quality of Health Care in America (Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 2000). 533 K Taxis and N. Barber, "Ethnographic Study of Incidence and Severity of Intravenous Drug Errors," British Medical Journal 326 (2003). 534 S.M Dovey et al., "A Preliminary Taxonomy of Medical Errors in Family Practice.," Quality and Safety in Health Care 11, no. 3 (2002). 535 Kohn, Corrigan, and Donaldson, eds., To Err Is Human: Building a Safer Health System. 536 S.N. Weingart et al., "Epidemiology of Medical Error," British Medical Journal 320 (2000). 537 D.W. Bates et al., "The Costs of Adverse Drug Events in Hospitalized Patients," Journal of the American Medicine Association 277 (1997). 538 Kohn, Corrigan, and Donaldson, eds., To Err Is Human: Building a Safer Health System. 539 European Commission, Eurobarometer Medical Errors (2006 [cited 26 June 2006]); available from http://ec.europa.eu/health/ph_publication/eurobarometers_en.htm. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 169 Figure 7.1 Percentage of hospital patients concerned about serious medical errors. Greece* 75% 60% Poland UK 49% Slovenia 49% 47% EU-25 Hungary 42% Germany 42% 40% France 37% Netherlands 33% Denmark 30% Czech Republic Austria Sweden 24% 20% *Country with highest percentage of respondents stating ‘worried’ to ‘How worried should hospital patients be about serious medical errors?’ Alternative responses are ‘not worried’ and don’t know’ Source: Eurobarometer Medical Errors Survey January 2006 Part of the explanation for findings regarding perceptions of the likelihood of medical error could be any relevant personal experiences regarding errors or the lack thereof. Austrians have had very low rates of personal experiences (respondent or family suffering medical error) with adverse events either in a local hospital or as a result of medicine prescribed by a doctor. Figures 7.4 and 7.5 illustrate Austria’s position leading all of the EU-25 on these two questions. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 170 Figure 7.2 Percentage of respondents reporting a family member having suffered a medical error from a prescribed medicine Austria 7% Germany 7% Hungary 9% Netherlands 9% EU-25 11% France 11% Slovenia 11% UK 11% 14% Czech Republic 15% Italy 16% Poland 21% Denmark 23% Latvia* * Country with highest percentage of respondents stating ‘yes’ o ‘Have t you or a family member suffered a serious medical error from a medicine that was prescribed by a doctor?’ of the EU-25, accession countries (Bulgaria, Romania) and candidates countries (Croatia and Turkey) Source: Eurobarometer Medical Errors Survey January 2006 Figure 7.3 Percentage of respondents reporting a family member having suffered a medical error in a local hospital Austria 11% Germany 12% Hungary 12% Netherlands 17% Slovenia 17% EU-25 18% Italy 18% UK 18% Czech Republic 19% France 19% Poland Denmark Latvia* 28% 29% 32% * Country with highest percentage of respondents stating ‘yes’ t o ‘Have you or a family suffered a serous medical error in a local hospital?’ of the EU -25, accession countries (Bulgaria, Romania) and candidates countries (Croatia and Turkey) Source:Eurobarometer Medical Errors Survey January 2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 171 These responses demonstrate that hospital incidents occur more often than medicine-related errors. Using the questions regarding perceptions of the likelihood of a medical error occurring, this data can be used to shed some light on what appears to drive risk perceptions formulation. About 20% of individuals who saw medical errors as important had personally experienced a medical error in hospital whereas only 8% of those who expressed indifference towards the topic had personally experienced an error. When looking at trust levels for individual professional groups, most Europeans have confidence that their doctor, medical staff and dentist will not commit at an error while treating them. Respondents were most confident in their dentist with the EU-25 average being 74%. While Austria is above average for all three professional categories, there is still room for growth in the trust attached to medical professionals across Europe. Figure 7.6 shows the varying degrees of confidence amongst the EU-25 for doctors and other medical professionals. Finnish citizens (responses not depicted on the graph) have the highest level of confidence in both categories (as well as with dentists). In sum, this new Eurobarometer survey demonstrates that medical errors are perceived by Europeans as a problem and citizens are well aware of their occurrence as 78% have read or heard about them. While the majority of respondents express confidence in health professionals, a sizeable sample does not. Although patients believe the health system holds responsibility for avoiding medical errors, this survey shows how Europeans do see the patient as having a role in decreasing his likelihood of becoming a medical error statistic. Figure 7.4 Confidence that doctors and medical staff would not make a medical error to harm them Medical Staff Doctors France 86% Austria 84% UK Hungary 77% 77% 76% 73% Netherlands 72% EU-25 69% Italy 68% 72% 68% 61% 65% 61% Slovenia Greece* 74% 63% Germany Poland 82% 79% Czech Republic Latvia 86% 59% 36% 34% 25% 38% 36% 24% * Country with lowest percentage of the population expressing co nfidence in both doctors and medical staff in the EU-25, accession countries (Bulgaria, Romania) and candidates countries (Croatia and Turkey) Source: Eurobarometer Medical Errors Survey January 2006 Current debate on the topic focuses on thinking about systems to avoid the occurrence of medical errors. Efforts now concentrate on promoting a culture of patient safety by encouraging teamwork and communication about adverse events.540 Quick response and the recognition of early warning signs also play key roles in preventing the potential long-term negative impacts of medical errors. The surgical oncology and general surgery intensive-care units at Johns Hopkins Hospital implemented a safety scheme that had staff follow eight steps to reduce patient safety concerns. This program resulted in a one-day 540 D. McCarthy and D. Blumenthal, "Committed to Safety: Ten Case Studies on Reducing Harm to Patients," (New York: Commonwealth Fund, 2006). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 172 decrease in average patient length-of-stay and 43 less catheter-related infections annually saving eight lives. This success demonstrates how creating cultures of safety in the workplace and improving teamwork across hospital staff can save both lives and money. The Missouri Baptist Medical Center in St. Louis, Missouri initiated a rapid response system to early signs of declining patient health to avoid acute crises. This system has resulted in a 15% reduction in cardiac arrests for the 489-bed hospital and a 3.95% decline in the hospital’s mortality rate.541 In the United Kingdom, the National Patient Safety Agency was established in 2001 with the aim to improve patient safety by reducing the risk of harm through medical errors through the promotion of a culture of learning from adverse events. This followed the publication of a Department of Health report – An Organization with a Memory – highlighting the human and financial costs of medical errors. The Agency operates an annual national system of reporting adverse events. Data are held anonymously and disseminated across the country in order to look retrospectively at incidents to determine what happened, how, and why. The Agency also offers resources such as learning tools for NHS staff to help raise awareness of patient safety issues. Similar organizations exist in Canada – the Canadian Patient Safety Institute – set up in 2003; and Australia – the Australian Patient Safety Foundation. Patient safety can be improved through various efforts. Education is one way – through formal pre-and postgraduate training, and in experiential learning including continuing professional development (CPD). Modern professional training courses in patient safety ought to demonstrate a culture of safety, one which: acknowledges and learns from error; encourages all to improve quality and safety; and is supportive of all personnel to protect patient safety, regardless of rank.542 Rules and regulations can also be used to improve patient safety, for example through evidence based practice (EBP). Some countries, for instance the United Kingdom through the National Institute of Health and Clinical Excellence (NICE), are increasingly incorporating EBP into their guidelines. Also on an international level, a World Alliance for Patient Safety was formed in 2002 which passed a resolution urging the World Health Organization to develop global clinical norms and standards. However it is important to highlight that even when guidelines or protocols are available, health care professionals have been shown to deviate from them; therefore it is crucial that rules in health care that are designed to influence behaviour must be understood and accepted by those expected to use them.543 7.2.1 Patient safety in Austria Patient safety is defined as “the avoidance, prevention and amelioration of adverse outcomes or injuries stemming from the processes of health care”. Events include “errors”, “deviations” and “accidents”. Safety emerges from the interaction of the components of the system, it does not reside in a person, device or department. Improving safety depends on learning how safety emerges from the interactions of the components. Patient safety is a subset of healthcare quality”.544 Austria does not have an own national agency to ensure patient safety. In the course of the health care reform 2005 the Federal Ministry of Health and Women put a special emphasis on the topic of patient safety. The Quality in health care Act defines patient safety in § 2 (4) as “measures to prevent adverse 541 Ibid. Amanda Howe, "Patient Safety: Eductation, Training and Professional Development," in Patient Safety: Research into Practice, ed. K Walshe and R Boaden (Berkshire: Open University Press, 2006). 543 T Claridge, D Parker, and G Cook, "Pathways to Patient Safety: The Use of Rules and Guidelines in Health Care," in Patient Safety: Research into Practice, ed. K Walshe and R Boaden (Berkshire: Open University Press, 2006). 544 Cooper, J.B., Sorensen, A.V., Anderson, S.M., Zipperer, L.A., Blum, L.N., Blim, J.F. (2001). Current research on Patient Safety in the United States. Final Report. Health Systems Research. Inc. Subcontract # 290-95-2000. National Patient Safety Foundation. In Holzer, E., Thomeczek, C., Hauke, E., Conen, D., Hochreutener, M.A. (2005). Patient Safety- guide for handling risks in the health care sector. Facultas. Vienna, pp. 171 542 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 173 outcomes (actions, omissions, other incidents), which may harm the patient”. Beginning in the Nineties national projects on quality were initiated and quality assurance became very important. A great number of projects was brought to life, some of them placing a special focus on patient safety: handling adverse events in patient care – “error culture and error management”, optimising the use of antibiotics, prevention and monitoring of medication errors based on the Med-Safe Model, ANISS project to document and monitor nosocomial infections, quality reporting, definition of quality criteria related to structures within the framework of the Austrian Structural Plan for health. Due to the Quality in health care Act the Federal Minister of Health was given the authority to enact a range of ordinances, amongst these also in the field of patient safety. It will be interesting to see as to which extent she makes use of her competence. The future federal institute for quality in health care will most likely also be involved in patient safety. Information systems for patient safety were i.e. are built up in the course of the above mentioned projects (e.g. in the quality reporting project, for the monitoring of adverse effects of medicines, for the Med-Safe project, for the haemovigilance register, databases for complaints in hospitals, etc.). National legislation for medical negligence545 In case of damages resulting from medical treatment or omission, two avenues of approach may be chosen. One is the judicial approach and the other is the extrajudicial approach.546 In order to receive compensation, the damaged patient can appeal to the civil courts. Before a lawyer institutes a procedure of civil law he often presses charges against the physician and effects an expert opinion which may be relevant for possible further procedures according to civil law. Patient lawyers are not entitled to appeal to courts of justice. In the course of an extrajudicial proceeding the patient lawyer, who aims to receive a compensation payment, can choose the option of appealing to the liability insurance of the hospital carrier or of the treating physician. Partially also professional bodies (for doctors, dentists) have established arbitration boards to handle extrajudicial settlements. These are either located at the regional Medical Chambers or are run in co-operation with the federal government or federal hospitals. An extrajudicial settlement has advantages for patients, courts, health care providers and consumer protection organizations. Liability may be based in misconduct of the physician such as a treatment error or a lack of counselling. In general it is important to distinguish between liability based on penal law or on civil law. The consequence of penal misconduct can, under certain circumstances, be a penal process and possibly even a penal conviction. The legal basis of penal liability is the book of penal law. Offences according to penal law are involuntary manslaughter according to § 81, bodily injury caused by negligence according to § 88 or arbitrary treatment according to § 110. Civil liability obliges the physician to provide compensation for his misconduct. Compensation can be linked to a contract (treatment contract with the physician or the hospital whereby the hospital carrier is liable for the physician as assistant according to § 1313a ABGB547) or to an offence (not based on a contractual relationship but based in conducting treatment). Both claims can be made at the same time. Premises which the patient has to fulfil in order to receive compensation for experienced harm/damage (financial or non-financial) are, according to the ABGB damage (§§ 1293, 132527 ABGB), causality, fault (§ 1299 ABGB, benchmark for diligence of the physician § 49 Doctors’ law) and illegality (§ 1295). The physician can guard himself against civil liability by signing up for liability 545 Vienna Medical Chamber. Liability. accessed at http://www.aekwien.at/665.html on 19/03/2006 Riegler, A.. (2002). Main features of the physician liability in civil law with respect to treatment errors considering the current legal situation. In Meggeneder, O., Hengl, W. Eds. The informed patient. Linz 546 Zimmer, D. (2002). Extrajudicial conflict settlement in the relationship physician-patient. In Meggeneder, O., Hengl, W. Eds. The informed patient. Linz 547 ABGB= Allgemeines Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch = General Civil Law Book LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 174 insurance for physicians; this is not possible for penal liability. Issues related to limitation of actions are regulated in § 1489 of the ABGB. It is evident that patient safety is a topic of increasing importance in the ordinance on quality assurance (ordinance of the Austrian Medical Chamber on the quality assurance of medical treatment provided by ambulatory physicians in their practices and in group-practices – QS-VO 2006 according to § 118c Doctors’ law 1998 BGBl 169/98 idF BGBl I Nr. 179/2004) in which § 8 “criteria for quality related to processes for physicians in their practices”, as part of standard Z6 “Adverse events/patient safety”, the following is stated: “Adverse events are discussed with all (potentially) involved co-workers. The aim is to find the reason for the event. Measures are implemented to avoid a recurring of the event. The patient affected by the adverse event will, after consultation of the liability insurance of the physician, according to § 58a para.2 Doctors’ Law, be informed demonstrably by him/her about the event”. Reporting of medical errors, access to information about the quality of services Austria has so far not defined a national concept for the reporting of medical errors. For some sub-areas systems and structures have already been established a couple of years ago (legal obligation to report adverse effects of medicines, establishment of a haemovigilance register). From the viewpoint of the Federal Ministry of Health and Women the Project “ Handling errors” (in the realm of the project “patient safety in Austrian hospitals”) represents the first comprehensive discussion of the topic.548 The aim was to find out how errors are dealt with in Austria. Initially the current level of knowledge was assessed; in a second step four hospitals were chosen which were observed more closely. The institute for palliative care and organizational ethics at the University of Klagenfurt was consigned to undertake this research. Various hypotheses were generated and studied. A description of the existing error culture was provided as well as a definition of requirements to establish a modern error culture. Critical factors for success were listed and following partial stages were planned, for instance the necessity of creating awareness and of social interaction with the topic, the execution of a qualitative sampling survey as well as the development of a training program “error culture” including relevant basic conditions (implementation of local and national reporting systems, execution of standardized surveys to be able to make comparisons, establishment of a competence centre for error culture and error management. Another project of the Ministry is the project to prevent and monitor medication errors based on the Med-Safe Model. Other organizations are also dealing with the topic of reporting/publication of medical errors: The Austrian association of general practitioners (Österreichische Gesellschaft für Allgemeinmedizin, ÖGAM) recommends physicians to take part in the German project “Every error counts” .549 The Hauptverband (Main Association of the Austrian Social insurance institutions) suggested the introduction of an anonymous error reporting system in 2005.550 The Austrian Medical Chamber was in principle not opposed to such as system however it was only prepared to engage in negotiations beginning in 2006.551 The Vienna Hospital Association (Wiener Krankenanstaltenverbund) started an area wide introduction of a complaint management for all urban hospitals and geriatric centres. The General hospital in Linz has introduced a 548 Dr. Arrouas (Federal Ministry of Health and Women, BMGF). Interview 13 January 2006 Dinges, S. (2005). About establishing a new error culture for handling errors in inpatient care. In E. Holzer, E., Thomeczek, C., Hauke, E., Conen, D., Hochreutener, M.A. (2005). Patient Safety- guide for handling risks in the health care sector. Facultas. Vienna. 549 Website of the German initiative www.jeder-fehler-zaehlt.de, an Austria-specific-assessment is planned 550 Endel, G. (2004). Patient safety and medical errors. accessed at http://www.sozialversicherung.at/mediaDB/77461.PDF on 20/03/2006 551 Austrian Medical Chamber. Error reporting system: Doctors prepared to talks after 2006. accessed at http://www.aerztekammer.at/index.php?id=000000000020050511145949&aid=xhtml&id=0000000000200505111459 49&type=module&noedit=true on 19/0372006 Martin, K. (2005). ″Patient lawyer following confrontation course.″ Ärztemagazin 21 accessed at http://www.medical-tribune.at/dynasite.cfm?dssid=4169&dsmid=64407&dspaid=492072 on 19/03/2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 175 database for complaints. The Vienna hospital association has furthermore recently introduced an error management system whereby errors and near misses may be filled into an internet platform anonymously without having to fear sanctions. The federal hospital in Feldkirch has already some time ago started a new IT system which is called CIRS (Critical Incident reporting system).552 Apart from institutional approaches/projects, numerous individual initiatives related to patient safety are exercised by people such as Prof. Pateisky (AKH Vienna553) – gynaecology, or Prof. Koller (Medical University of Vienna) – nosocomial infections. Information and/or data on medical errors is most likely available in quite a few health care institutions (e.g. hospitals), social insurance carriers or at the Ministry, it is however not made available to the public. Medical errors are unfortunately communicated to patients mostly in the context of single events, whereby the importance of factual reporting takes a back seat. Institutions such as patient lawyers report in a reliable way. In Austria 499 people received compensation which amounted to €4,610,826.00554 in total. From the 451 cases which were referred to the patient compensation fund, 99 have been decided favourably.555 Based on § 27a para.5 of the Federal law on hospitals and spas556 a patient compensation fund557 was established.558 The fund aims to complement the existing compensation law and to optimise it. The fund is used in cases in which a legal claim does not face chances of success. It is funded solely by patients who pay a sum of €0.73 per day spent in hospital.559 The regulation is heavily criticised for the fact that patients have to pay for their own compensation. In 2004 country-wide 451 patients claimed compensation, 78% were assessed favourably. In total payments in the range of €3,418,234.21 were made.560 The department for Evidence Based Medicine at the Hauptverband estimates that, based on international publications, 245,000 incidences and 2,900-6,800 iatrogenic deaths occur in Austrian hospitals.561 Even if these figures represent, according to the author, a worst case estimate, they should however draw attention to the topic and justify additional initiatives related to quality management. Until recently the legal- as well as the structural framework for the establishment of a standardized error reporting system did not exist. Equally there was no error culture or awareness for a discussion of the topic. Any other information related to quality is available to patients only in a limited way. Patients receive information on health care services from a range of different sources (Internet, brochures, television and recommendations of family/friends/acquaintances). In addition they are informed by physicians and other health care professionals about existing treatment options and are referred to other health care institutions (medical specialists, laboratories, hospitals, etc.) in the course of treatment. Information for patients is mostly restricted to aspects of quality related to structures (range of services available), on rare occasions it is possible for the patient to estimate the outcome or the risk (e.g. risk of an operation in a chosen hospital). 552 Poznansiki, U. (2006). ″Error management: how to deactivate bombs.″ Clinicum 5, accessed at http://www.medizin-medien.info/dynasite.cfm?dssid=4171&dsmid=74036&dspaid=575495 553 AKH= Allgemeines Krankenhaus=General Hospital 554 Paid by liability insurance (77%), by the arbitration board at the Medical Chamber (15%), the arbitration board of the federal state (2%), and the hardship-fund (Härtefonds) (6%) 555 ARGE PA (Working group of patient lawyers) (2004). Austria Report 2004. Presentation by Martin Kräftner (Office of the patient lawyer of Lower Austria) 556 BGBl 5/2001 557 Enacting legislation of the respective federal laws 558 Patient Lawyer of Lower Austria (2004). Patient compensation fund, Activity report. St. Pölten. 559 A maximum of 28 days per year 560 ARGE PA, Working group of patient lawyers (2004). Austria Report 2004. Presentation by Martin Kräftner (Office Patient lawyer Lower Austria) 561 Endel, G. (2004). Patient safety and medical errors. accessed at http://www.sozialversicherung.at/mediaDB/77461.PDF on 20/03/2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 176 Information such as mortality statistics are available for the hospital area (via the LKF system), the data is handled very carefully, an exchange only takes place amongst the health care providers, for instance via the DIAG database of the Ministry. Access to this system is handled in a very restrictive way. For ambulatory care (physicians) little data exists, possibly at some of the associations of medical specialties. This data is also not published.562 Patient safety is stated as one of the core principles in the newly established quality law of 2005, giving the topic more significance. The Quality in Health Care Act announces for the patient that he will have access to transparent information on health care related aspects in the future. During the elaboration of the law experiences from other countries were taken into consideration.563 The demand of the patient lawyers for a new patient right to increase transparency of quality related data has been met. Increased transparency should be ensured by means of a periodic quality reporting system which is currently being established. § 6 (3) of the Quality in health care Act states “The Federal Minister of Health and Women has to, with respect to improving transparency, report the intensity of active participation of actors in the Austrian quality system, to the interested public in a suitable way. Furthermore he has to ensure that appropriate feedback systems to those responsible for quality reporting are developed”. The results as well as the final report on the first Austrian quality report have been given to the Ministry but not been published yet. At the same time the Ministry is setting up a website for patient safety. The further development of the topic of transparency in health care with respect to quality information will depend strongly on the political courage of the decision makers. In Austria various institutions representing patient interests i.e. enforcing patient rights exist which patients can approach when in need of information or equally in the case of complaints or legal cases. Safety of the blood supply564 In Austria the safety of blood and blood products is regulated by a number of laws. Legal foundations are the Blood Safety Law (Blutsicherheitsgesetz -1999 - BSG BGBl I 1999/44 i. d. F. BGBl I 1999/119)) together with the associated Blood Donation Regulation (Blutspendeverordnung BSV BGBl II 1999/100)), the Pharmaceutical Law (Arzneimittelgesetz §§ 75, 75a, 75b)) including the corresponding regulations, in particular, the Pharmaceutical Plant Regulations (Arzneimittelbetriebsordnung) 2005 and the regulations pertaining to medication produced from human blood, the Federal Law for Hospitals and Clinics (Bundesgesetz über Krankenanstalten und Kuranstalten), as well as, at a European level, the “haemovigilance565-guidelines“ – Guideline 2005/61/EG, which were agreed upon on 30th September 2005. Beyond that there are minimum standards for blood depots566 (published by the Ministry of Social Security and Generations (BMSG) in June 2002), as well as, recommendations on haemovigilance in the Guide to the preparation, use and quality assurance of blood components of the Council of Europe (Chapter 30). By request of the BMSG an Austrian haemo-vigilance register was set up in the Austrian Institute for Health Care (ÖBIG) in January 2003. ÖBIG has a central position for the notification of undesirable effects of medication in connection with the transfusion of blood and blood products. The aim of haemo-vigilance is quality assurance and quality improvement, as well as, the minimisation of risks and dangers in the 562 Dr. Fronaschütz (Federal Ministry of Health and Women, BMGF). Interview 21 December 2005 ibid 564 Dr. Johann Kurz (Federal Ministry of Health and Women, BMGF). Telephone interview September 2005 Austrian Federal Institute for Health Care (ÖBIG) (2005). Haemovigilance in Austria. Commissioned by the BMGF. Vienna. BMGF (2004). Healthcare report Austria.Vienna For further information see www.bmgf.at und www.ris.bka.gv.at 565 Haemovigilance describes the compilation and processing of undesired effects of blood and blood products, as well as, a monitoring system, which documents the transfusion chain from donor to patient. 566 The recording procedure in the hospital is regulated through these (who reports what, when, to whom, and how often) 563 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 177 aforementioned areas. The reporting system is supervised by ÖBIG and the affiliated Contamination Information Centre (Vergiftungsinformationszentrale, VIZ). 7.2.2 Patient rights in Austria Patient rights are rooted in numerous laws, amongst others, in the General Civil Law Book (Allgemeinen Bürgerlichen Gesetzbuch) (§§ 1295, 1325, 1167, 1489 ABGB), in the Penal Law Book (Strafgesetzbuch) (§§ 88, 90, 95, 110, 184 StGB), in the Law for Hospitals and Clinics (Krankenanstalten und Kuranstalten Gesetz) (§§ 5a KAG, further details in the executive legislation of the federal states) in the Doctor’s Law (Ärztegesetz) (§§ 48, 49, 51, 54) as well as the laws of various health professions, in the General Social Insurance Law (Allgemeines Sozialversicherungsgesetz) as well as its special laws (Sondergesetzen), in the Pharmaceutal Law (Arzneimittelgesetz), in the Medical Product Law (Medizinproduktegesetz), in the Hospitalisation Act (Unterbringungsgesetz), in the Law for Reproductive Medicine (Fortpflanzungsmedizingesetz), in the Aids Law (Aidsgesetz) and in the Genetic Technology Law (Gentechnikgesetz). Patient charta For the first time, in 1993, in a comprehensive amendment to the Hospital Law, a paragraph with the heading Patient Rights was included (§ 5 KAG). Points particularly worth mentioning are the right to treatment, self-determination, clarification and information, the right to look at their medical records, protection of privacy, and the right to a dignified death. Because of severe fragmentation a consolidation of the legal policies in this area was called for. A concise and, for lay persons, easy to understand, summary of the most important patient rights was issued in 1999 within the framework of a contract between the federation and the nine federal states in accordance with Art. 15a B-VG (BGBl I 1999/195), Agreement for the assurance of Patient Rights, Patient charta (Vereinbarung zur Sicherstellung der Patientenrechte, Patientencharta). The first federal state to sign the agreement was Carinthia. Contents of the patient charter are ensuring personal rights and human dignity, ban on discrimination based on types of illnesses, the right to treatment and care (equal access, proper implementation), respect for dignity and integrity, self-determination and information and the right to documentation. Moreover there are special terms for children, directives on the representation of patient interests as well as the enforcement of claim for damages. The creation of the patient charter has brought with it numerous consequential actions/activities, which have led or will lead to further improvement of patient rights. In the meantime the patient charter has been signed by all federal states and is therefore valid country-wide. Advance directive Every citizen in Austria is entitled to set up an advance directive and to thereby proclaim their will i.e. decide on what will happen with him in case he is severely ill and not able to comprehend, to take decisions or to communicate. By means of an advance directive the patient can reject certain medical treatment, the area of responsibility does however not cover any measures of nursing. There are no formal requirements, but a universal form for advance directives was developed as well as various brochures and guidebooks567 (e.g. of the hospice umbrella organization568 or of the Patient lawyer in Lower Austria569) 567 In co-operation of the BMGF, the Ministry of Justics, the umbrella organization for hospice care in Austria, patient lawyers, the Medical Chamber and other institutions. 568 Hospice care in Austria. Information on advance directives. accessed at http://www.hospiz.at/ 569 Patient Lawyer of Lower Austria (2002). Advance directive – Patient guide. St. Pölten. Accessed at http://www.patientenanwalt.com/pdf/1_Ratgeber_Patientenverfuegung.pdf on 10/09/2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 178 The legal basis is primarily the Advance Directive Act, which came into existence on June 1 2006; furthermore the Patient Charta, the Hospital Act or the Penal Law Book. The new federal law regulates the preconditions for the development of a living will, its consequences and possible contents.570 Institutions for patients (information, complaints) In Austria there are diverse institutions which represent patient rights or enforce patient rights, and to which the patient can turn for information, or in cases of complaints or disputes. Here the independent, directivefree, autonomous institutions of patient lawyers (also known as patient representatives), which since the 90ies have been established in every federal state by the federal state legislator play an important role. Their geographical limits extend over the whole federal state (jurisdiction dependent on the place where the incident took place and not the place of residence of the patient), the area of competence varies from region to region (all are responsible for hospitals, some for nursing homes and/or doctors in their own practices). In some federal states the patient lawyer is also a lawyer for areas related to nursing (e.g. in Lower Austria), in other federal states these two areas of responsibility are separated. In Vienna, for instance, the merging of the two institutions is currently discussed. The help of patient lawyers can be called upon free of charge. Their duties cover advisory services, clarification and information, mediating in conflicts/disputes, as well as, assistance with out of court claims following treatment errors. Public relations work is of great importance. Since mid 2001 the supervision of the patient compensation fund571 falls into the area of responsibility of the patient lawyers. Patient lawyers have merged to a single consortium (ARGE PA) in order to represent patient interests at a national level and to coordinate the activities of individual patient lawyers. Representatives of patient lawyers are members of numerous bodies at national and regional level. Besides the patient lawyers there are other places which represent the interests of patients, such as the Chamber of Labour (Arbeiterkammer) (for insured and their dependents, also in the field of social insurance), who offer an advisory service for their members as well as represent them in court. In some social insurance funds ombudsmen/women were appointed, whose area of responsibility include legal issues relating to social insurance. Following the directives in § 11e of the Hospital Law (Krankenanstaltengesetz), some hospitals have appointed ombudsmen for their patients, who are at the patient’s disposal for information, suggestions, or complaints. Arbitration boards and public attorney set up by some chambers of doctors should also be mentioned. In part patient lawyers and arbitration boards work very closely together. In addition more than 1,600 self help groups572 make an invaluable contribution in supporting patients’ concerns. Since the year 2004 patients can also turn to the non-profit patient-initiative in health care (PatientInnenInititiative im Gesundheitswesen, PinG), which helps patients with urgent problems, offers juridical advice and counselling for other areas not within the remit of patient lawyers. Furthermore they provide assistance in dealing with private issues and activities as well as supporting individuals by giving them comprehensive information about various new developments and drawbacks in the health care sector.573 570 Bachinger, G. (2006). Helping patients, the new Advance Directive Act in Austria. Patient lawyer of Lower Austria. August 2006. accessed at http://www.patientenanwalt.com/pdf/0608_Letter_Bachinger_Das_neue_Patientenverfuegungs-Gesetz.pdf on 10/09/2006 571 Not a refund, rather a supplementation and optimisation of liability as set out in civil law. Legal basis § 27a Abs. 5 and 6 of the Federal Law for Hospitals and Spas (BGBl. I Nr. 90/2002) as well as regional specifications (up to 2003). 572 Self-help-groups, accessed at www.selbsthilfe.at 573 No author (2006).Self-help-groups: Advice and help. DA, Die Apotheke June, pp.20 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 179 Use of these services: patient lawyers574 Table 7.2 Legal cases of patient lawyers (Austria total) Hospitals Nursing homes Physician practices Social insurance Others Total complaints 2003 3374 163 609 201 926 5273 2004 3677 288 618 169 1003 5755 Source: ARGE PA (Working group of patient lawyers) (2004). Austria Report 2004. Presentation by Martin Kräftner In 2004, in hospitals, most legal cases were registered in the departments of surgery, accident surgery, internal medicine and gynaecology. Figure 7.5 Distribution of cases in hospital departments in Austria, 2004 Distribution of cases in hospital departments - Austria 2004 Surgery; 790 Others; 856 Neurosurgery, Anaesthesiology/ Intensive care; 71 Ophtalmology; 67 Ortolaryngology; 252 Gynaecology; 342 Neurology; 144 Internal Medicine; 369 Urology; 69 Pediatrics; 103 Accident Surgery; 609 Orthopedics; 252 Psychiatry; 73 Source: ARGE PA (Working group of patient lawyers) (2004). Austria Report 2004. Presentation by Martin Kräftner For doctors in their own practices most legal cases concerned the following specialist areas: dentistry, general medicine, orthopaedics, and gynaecology. 574 ARGE PA (Working group of patient lawyers) (2004). Austria Report 2004. Presentation by Martin Kräftner (Office of the patient lawyer of Lower Austria) LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 180 Figure 7.6 Distribution of cases among doctors in surgeries in Austria Distribution of cases amongst doctors in surgeries Austria 2004 without Tyrol General Practitioners; 92 Others; 86 Gynaecologists; 47 Doctors of Internal Medicine; 21 Pediatricians; 5 Dentists; 196 Orthopaedic Surgeons; 62 Ophtalmologists; 28 Emergency services, Ambulance; 40 Dermatologists; 27 Radiologists; 14 Source: ARGE PA (Working group of patient lawyers) (2004). Austria Report 2004. Presentation by Martin Kräftner Ombudswomen of the regional sickness fund of Vienna The Ombuds-Office of the regional sickness fund in Vienna is staffed with two persons, with the Ombudswomen Gertraude Jung and her co-worker Ms. Heidi Exl. In 2005 2,845 contacts were registered, adding about 960 not yet registered contacts. In total this results in an increase of about 16% compared to 2004 whereby increases in email contacts were particularly strong (+60%). Figure 7.7 Legal cases of the ombudswomen of the Vienna sickness fund, 2005 2004 - 2737 Fälle (+ ca. 960 nicht erfasste) = 3697 2005 - 2845 Fälle (+ ca. 1440 nicht erfasste) = 4285 1800 1600 1400 1200 telefonisch 1000 schriftlich 800 persönlich 600 per E-Mail 400 nicht erfasste 200 0 1756 245 359 377 2004 960 1683 250 312 600 1440 2005 Fälle = cases, telefonisch= on the telephone, schriftlich = in writing, persönlich=in person, per E-Mail = via E-mail, nicht erfasste= not registered Source: Vienna sickness fund, report of the ombuds-office for the year 2005, received 19/0672006 (via email) LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 181 Cases of the Ombuds-Office were categorised according to the relevant organizational entities at the regional sickness fund of Vienna. From the figure below it can be inferred that most of the cases are related to the medical field, then to the district offices, treatment economics and contributions. Changes to the previous year are all below 3%. Figure 7.8 Legal cases of the ombudswomen of the Vienna sickness fund, 2005 related departments betroffene Organisationseinheiten 30% Ärztl.Dion/Med.Dienst 25% Bezirksstellen Behandlungsökonomie 20% Beitragsbereich Leistungsabteilung 15% Eigene Einrichtungen 10% Dion sonstige Abt. externe 30% 18% 13% 12% 11% 4% 5% 2% 2% 8% 0% Ärztl. Dion/Med. Dienst= medical management, Bezirksstellen=district offices, Behandlungsökonomie=treatment economics, Beitragsbereich= constibutions, Leistungsabteilung=benefits department, Eigene Einrichtungen= integrated institutions, Dion= management, sonstige Abteilungen= other departments, externe= external Source: Vienna sickness fund, report of the ombuds-office for the year 2005, received 19/0672006 (via email) The Ombuds-Office was able to provide help to 31% of the contacts, 61% of enquiries were answered by providing information, for 6% of the enquiries it was not possible to help the person who referred to the Ombuds-Office. In 2005 27% of all enquiries were undertaken by pensioners, 24% by representatives of the active working population, 15% by insured with another sickness fund, 11% by unemployed, 10% by dependants, 6% by persons without health insurance coverage, 3% by voluntary insured and persons receiving maternity benefits as well as 1% by of employers. In comparison to the previous year there are hardly any deviations. A detailed table of the cases during the past 8 years can be found in the Appendix 16. 7.3 Patient choice Individuals can exercise choice at various decision points within a health system. Regarding insurance, individuals may be able to choose to have insurance or not, choose between public or private insurance, or between individual insurance funds. Choice of provider may relate to the first contact provider, general practitioner, specialist, hospital, or of a doctor in the hospital. Finally, patients may have some degree of choice of treatment, for instance they may have the option to refuse treatment, type of treatment, time of treatment, and the setting.575 However, there are many possible constraints to choice; therefore it is rare for choices to be completely ‘free’. Explicit constraints may arise from restricting choice to: specific groups of people, such as high income earners; a limited range of options, such as providers within a geographical area; a particular point in time; and those who are willing to pay an extra fee.576 Implicit constraints to choice may relate to 575 576 S Thomson and A Dixon, "Choices in Health Care: The European Experience," Euro Observer 2004. Ibid. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 182 contextual factors such as: individual’s knowledge and information; health system capacity; proximity to services; ability to pay; cultural or institutional norms; institutional responses to particular incentives such as risk selection by competing insurance funds. Generally social health insurance systems offer a greater level of choice of provider to the population than tax-based health systems. In Austria patients are offered unlimited choice of general practitioner, ambulatory specialist, hospital and nursing home. The only country in Western Europe that offers individuals a choice of public or private insurance coverage is Germany. In Austria individuals do not have choice of their insurance fund – this is determined on the basis of occupation and/or region of residence. Figure 7.9 Perceived choice of GP/doctor in Austria vs. European average, 2004 100% 86% 90% 80% 72% 70% 60% ESS-average 50% Austria 40% 28% 30% 20% 14% 10% 0% Enough choice Not enough choice Source: European Social Survey 2004577 Data from the European Social Survey from 2004 ask questions about perceived choice of physician. Far more respondents in Austria reported adequate choice of doctor than the average across all countries surveyed (Figure 7.11). Disaggregating the countries highlights that individuals are most satisfied in terms of patient choice in Belgium, Switzerland, France and Germany, and least in Greece, Iceland, Portugal and Ukraine (Figure 7.12). It is important to highlight the difficulties in comparing perceptions and opinions across countries; differing cultures, religion, history, and socio-economic context may significantly influence (and bias) the responses in surveys. Recent reforms have taken place in Belgium, Germany and the Netherlands which involved increasing consumer choice of sickness fund and/or increasing the funds’ financial responsibility in order to improve efficiency.578 The reforms of 1992 in the Netherlands allowed people to enrol in any sickness fund they wished regardless of their geographical location.579 However, the effects of this reform were limited by the small price differentials between competing funds, which may not outweigh the transaction costs of switching. In order to improve efficiency, Dutch sickness funds were permitted to contract selectively with physicians and 577 The European Social Survey includes 24 countries: Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, Ukraine. 578 W Van de Ven et al., "Risk Adjustment and Risk Selection on the Sickness Fund Insurance Market in Five European Countries," Health Policy 65 (2003). 579 F.T Schut, S Gress, and J. Wasem, "Consumer Price Sensitivity and Social Health Insurer Choice in Germany and the Netherlands," International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics 3, no. 2 (2003). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 183 other health care professionals in any geographic area.580 However, their freedom to negotiate contracts was limited by rigidly defined entitlements in the health insurance legislation and government price regulation. In Germany, freedom of choice of sickness fund was granted in 1996. Since then, fund switching has become quite common, and the evidence suggests that funds are competing on the basis of price.581 However, funds are not permitted to selectively contract, or choose the most efficient providers and hospitals for preferred cooperation, therefore impeding any efficiency gains and leaving risk-selection as the most effective tool to maintain competitiveness. While many believe the lack of selective contracting is the main obstacle to achieving competition and enhanced efficiency, others contend that high transaction costs and lack of managerial experience in the medical profession are more important.582 In order to ensure fairness, risk-adjusted premium subsidies were implemented alongside reforms introducing choice of insurance fund. The factors that the risk-adjustment mechanisms were based on, however, were inaccurate predictors of future health care needs. More specifically, the risk-adjustment scheme in Germany only accounted for crude indicators such as income, age, reception of disability insurance and entitlement for sickness allowance. Therefore, despite these attempts to preserve solidarity, the sickness funds were left with financial incentives to select profitable consumers. This selection not only undermines the equity goals, but also those of efficiency. Recent reforms in Germany sought to remedy this problem of risk selection, including compensating sickness funds that have high cost members, in addition to introducing managed care (Disease Management Programs) which provides incentives for sickness funds to insure people with chronic illness. The experiences in these three countries highlight the need for an appropriate, improved risk adjustment model. More specifically, health-based risk adjustment mechanisms may help prevent selection, for example by adjusting for prior year expenditures, prior utilization, self-reported health information and mortality. Examples of these methods can be found in the US 583 and in the introduction of Pharmacy Costs Groups in the Netherlands584, which reduces the incentives for risk selection. 580 F.T Schut and E van Doorslaer, "Towards a Reinforced Agency Role of Health Insurers in Belgium and the Netherlands," Health Policy 48, no. 1 (1999). 581 Schut, Gress, and Wasem, "Consumer Price Sensitivity and Social Health Insurer Choice in Germany and the Netherlands." 582 P. Riemer-Hommel, "The Changing Nature of Contracts in German Health Care," Social Science and Medicine 55 (2002). 583 L.M. Greenwald, "Medicare Risk Adjusted Payments: From Research to Implementation," Health Care Financing Review 21, no. 3 (2000), G.C Pope, R.P Ellis, and A.S Ash, "Principal Inpatient Diagnostic Cost Group Model for Medicare Risk Adjustment," Health Care Financing Review 21, no. 3 (2000). 584 L.M Lamers, "Pharmacy Cost Groups: A Risk-Adjuster for Capitation Payments," Medical Care 34, no. 6 (1999). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 184 Figure 7.10 Perceived choice of GP/doctor in European countries Belgium 95% Switzerland 95% France 91% Germany 91% Luxembourg 88% Denmark 86% Ireland 86% Austria 86% Slovenia 80% Slovakia 79% Norway 78% 76% United Kingdom 74% Czech ESS-average 72% 70% Netherlands Hungary 68% 67% Poland Finland 64% Sweden 63% Estonia 62% Spain 61% 55% Greece Iceland 46% 41% Portugal Ukraine 19% 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% 120% Source: European Social Survey 2004 7.3.1 Choice in the Austrian health system Choice of insurer Austria has a system of statutory social insurance. The insurance is a legal requirement and is linked with the commencement of gainful employment liable for compulsory insurance. Coverage usually begins immediately, without a waiting period, and usually in the form of comprehensive coverage (including all branches of social insurance – health, accident, and pension insurance). The insured person can, with very few exceptions, neither opt out of insurance nor select the insurance fund, since this is also legally regulated. Affiliation is, on the one hand, associated with the type of employment and on the other hand regional criteria (location of the workplace, location of residence). There is no competition between the insurance funds. This means that selection according to risk is not possible. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 185 The legal foundations of the Austrian social insurance may be found in the following federal laws and their numerous amendments: * General Social Insurance Law (Allgemeines Sozialversicherungsgesetz, ASVG) – for employees, apprentices, employee peers etc. * Civil Service – Sickness and Accident Insurance Law (Beamten-Kranken- und Unfallversicherungsgesetz, B-KUVG) – sickness and/or accident insurance for persons employed in the public sector and similar, governed by public law are, on the basis of this employment status, entitled to special retirement terms. * Commercial Social Insurance Law (Gewerbliches Sozialversicherungsgesetz, GSVG) – for self-employed persons in the commercial sector. * Federal law regarding social insurance for freelance, self employed persons (Bundesgesetz über die Sozialversicherung freiberuflich selbständig Erwerbstätiger, FSVG) – for doctors, pharmacists and patent lawyers * Social Insurance Law for Farmers (Bauern-Sozialversicherungsgesetz, BSVG) – for self-employed persons in farming and forestry In addition to the above stated laws contractual agreements such as collective and individual contracts play a very important role in Austrian social insurance. Choice within the social health insurance system Options are very limited in the Austrian social insurance system. Since affiliation to a particular insurance fund is governed by law, a change to an alternative fund occurs in only a few cases e.g. when particular insurance requirements are no longer met, a change of job, becoming unemployed585 or when, as far as personal circumstances allow, a private insurance is opted for to replace the compulsory insurance. Those insured with the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (Sozialversicherungsanstalt der Gewerblichen Wirtschaft, SVA) have the most options available. In 2000 freelance members of chambers were given the opportunity to opt out of the compulsory social insurance (health and/or pension insurance) (§ 5 GSVG). At the end of the 3rd quarter 2005 freelancers constituted about 8.6% of all those insured.586 Pre-requisite for this was an application from the appropriate trade association. They had to provide evidence of an equivalent health insurance coverage, whether it be a compulsory insurance in accordance with GSVG (§ 14ab), or a private collective or individual insurance (or further insurance) in accordance with ASVG.587 Only doctors are not required to choose one of the three above mentioned options, but rather they receive commensurate protection via the health care facility arranged by their representative agency. The occupational groups of doctors, pharmacists, lawyers, trustees, veterinarians, notaries, patent lawyers, and civil engineers have all applied for exemption from the GSVG health insurance, lawyers and civil engineers have also applied to opt out of pension insurance588. The options vary depending on whether the insured person carries out only freelance work or whether he also has another form of employment. Despite opting out, as already suggested, certain circumstances may still require a compulsory health insurance in accordance with § 14b GSVG. By the end of the 3rd quarter 2005, 2,319 people (approx. 6.4% of freelancers) opted for an insurance in accordance with § 14ab.589 Up to 2002, from the 4th year of self employment and as long as their income was above a certain limit (limit of allowance in kind), insured persons had the opportunity to claim benefits as those entitled to cash benefits (upgrade) this means they receive medical attendance, medication, dental treatment and dental 585 Recipients of health care benefits resulting from entitlement through unemployment insurance are, based on their place of residence, insured with the regional sickness fund 586 Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (SVA), statistics, received on 02/01/06 (via email) 587 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 588 Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (2005), Social Insurance Authority for Business, Introductory information (Erstinformation). Vienna. 589 Dr. Richter (Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business), information given 16 March 2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 186 prostheses as cash benefits (make the claim as if they are private patients).590 They receive a statutory amount as reimbursement. All other benefits (institutional care, curative care, etc.) are received as allowance in kind. Insured persons below this limit are entitled to allowance in kind. The 26th amendment of the GSVG (from 1.01.02) brought with it additional possibilities for those entitled to allowance in kind or cash benefits in order to better fit the insurance protection to individual needs (see § 85a GSVG). Those entitled to cash benefits could, for the first time, change, upon application, in part/or completely to an allowance in kind entitlement. Those entitled to allowance in kind could, against payment of an additional contribution (of varying amounts) acquire cash benefit entitlement591. At the end of 2002 there were 1,585 upgrades amongst those still actively working and 4,498 amongst pensioners (insured persons who opted voluntarily for a total entitlement to cash benefits).592 Table 7.3 Options for self-employed after 2002 ACTIVE PENSIONERS normal AIK half CB 60,76** half CB 2,00 full CB 75,94** normal CB normal AIK half CB 60,76** full CB 75,94** 31.12.2002* 31.12.2003 23.02.2004 31.12.2004 253,850 1,362 1,693 2,151 4,435 5,575 5,925 1,585 1,556 1,463 1,517 19,913 103,668 1,058 1,105 1,275 4,498 3,58 3,534 3,434 11.08.2005 3,229 6,333 1,713 1,42 3,367 Actively working incl. working pensioners *) Final status upgrade **) Value 2004 Source: Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business, received 16/03/2006 Categories: - Normal AIK: normal allowance in kind - Active half cash benefit (CB): Persons entitled to allowance in kind, who have opted for a cash benefit entitlement in hospital (2006 €64.02 per month) - Active half cash benefit for €2.00: Persons entitled to cash benefits, who have opted change back to allowance in kind for their medical attendance – retain their entitlement to cash benefits only for the hospital - Active full cash benefits: those who have opted for total entitlement to cash benefits (2006 €80.02) – this option is only possible for those entitled to allowance in kind Newly self-employed persons whose yearly income is not yet fixed and who are uncertain as to whether they will exceed certain insurance limits can submit an option for health and accident insurance (Opting-In). Exemption from the pension insurance however remains in place593. This insurance can be terminated by means of deregistration. This option was chosen by 5,168 people (about 14% of freelancers) by the end of the 3rd quarter 2005.594 Insured persons covered by a legally governed multiple insurance (several activities are carried out which are subject to compulsory insurance) are, primarily, able to choose which insurance fund they will use for which benefit. On July1, 2004 36,285 persons i.e. 1.2% of the employed had two or more occupations.595 Otherwise the service responsibility will comply with legal requirements. The insured person can however, 590 Certain advantages such as: authorization by a senior physician not required, compliance to RÖV, Directive on economic prescribing (Richtlinie über die ökonomische Verschreibweise) not required 591 Neumann, T. (2002), ″New options in the health insurance for businesses/ self-employed.″ Soziale Sicherheit 10, pp. 423-426 592 Dr. Richter (Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business), 16 March 2006 (via email) 593 Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business, accessed at http://esv-sva.sozvers.at on 10/03/2006 594 Dr. Richter (Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business). 16 March 2006 (via email) 595 Haydn, R. (2005), ″Multiple insurance in Austrian Social insurance, individual-related statistics 2004.″ Soziale Sicherheit 2, pp. 74-82. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 187 upon application, call on the services of another health insurance fund with whom he is insured. Some insured persons who in accordance with §5 GSVG have the opportunity of opting out still choose an insurance in accordance with the GSVG because then a multiple insurance with its many advantages becomes applicable. People without insurance cover have the opportunity of insuring themselves voluntarily. Voluntary insurance requires a formal application and can be secured for single or multiple branches of social insurance. In a survey conducted by the Austrian Association for Health Economics (Österreichische Gesellschaft für Gesundheitsökonomie, ÖGGÖ) in 2004, analysing the impact of the LKF System (Austrian DRG system for hospital funding), 600 experts from hospitals and other areas related to health care were asked if the insured population should have the option of choosing between the individual sickness funds and what impact this choice might have. Statutory health insurance should nevertheless be maintained. About 53% of the 110 experts who filled out the questionnaire favoured the option of choice to increase competition, roughly 55% considered it positive because it would lead to an increase in services for the insured and around 70% argued that it would result in a better personal assistance of the insured. Choice of private health insurance The role of private health insurance in Austria is not very dominant, mainly due to the comprehensive coverage by legally defined statutory health insurance. Reaching 2.4%596 of total health care expenditure the share of private health insurance is fairly low. It is primarily used to pay for better accommodation in private wards of hospitals, for free choice of doctors (only in private hospitals) and for reducing waiting times. Nevertheless private health insurance funds about 7%597 of the expenditure of public hospitals. In ambulatory care (doctors in surgeries) private health insurance is not of major significance. The market is dominated by few (8) market participants who are joined together in the Association of Insurance Companies (Verband der Versicherungsunternehmen, VVO) and have a total of 1,344 million Euro in premium revenues. UNIQA held a share of nearly 50% in 2004, Wiener Städtische of about 20%, Merkur and Generali each a little bit more or less than 13%. The remaining private health insurers each occupy shares of less than 3%. The largest items in terms of expenditure are payments for hospitals, dental care and physician services.598 The option of signing up for a substitutive private health insurance is only open to a small group of individuals, those who opted out of statutory social health insurance based on § 5 GSVG. Furthermore persons not covered through either compulsory or voluntary social health insurance. Choice of provider: physician The Austrian social insurance allows the insured person free choice of which doctor they visit. They can visit freelance doctors having a contract with one or several sickness funds, doctors in contract group practices, doctors in facilities provided by health insurance funds (ambulatory clinics), doctors in contract establishments (e.g. hospital outpatient departments) or private doctors (who do not have a contract with a sickness fund), doctors in private group practices, or doctors in private facilities across the whole of Austria.599 Freedom of choice can be exercised more readily in more highly populated areas than in rural areas primarily because the concentration of health care on offer is higher.600 Although the geographic distribution of contract doctors should, according to § 135 Abs. (2) ASVG, ensure that, as a rule, the choice of at least two doctors or group practices, which may be reached in reasonable time, may be called upon for treatment. 596 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 597 ibid 598 Association of (private) Insurance Companies (2005). Yearly report 2005, accessed at www.vvo.at, on 27/04/2006 599 Web portal of Austrian Social Insurance, accessed at www.sozialversicherung.at 600 Tomandl, T. (2005). What you always wanted to know about Social Insurance. Vienna, Manz. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 188 A restriction in the free choice of doctor is, according to OGH judgement, admissible in cases where the health insurance fund wants to restrict examinations with large scale equipment e.g. magnetic resonance examinations, to be carried out in specific contract facilities.601 Some sickness funds only allow the insured to directly visit one general practitioner and one specialist physician during a single billing period (as a rule 3 months), further specialist visits are possible by referral through the GP. This regulation varies among the health insurance funds, some even allow unlimited direct access to medical specialists (e.g. regional sickness fund in Tyrol, beginning January 2006). A change of contract doctor is only allowed after declaration of reasons for the change and with the approval of the health insurance fund. Furthermore the insured person is not permitted to consult several contract doctors in the same branch for the same condition at the cost of the health insurance.602 In certain cases, following an application, an exception can be made. When enlisting services at the expense of social insurance, the insured person is obliged to present his e-card as proof of entitlement. Choice of provider: hospital Basically the insured person is permitted to personally select the hospital at which he will receive inpatient treatment. Restrictions may arise because of reimbursement of transportation costs to the hospital, as generally, in case intramural care, in accordance with § 144 ASVG, is required the patient will be admitted to the nearest, federally funded hospital, having the necessary treatment facilities. The patient’s wishes (also with regards admission to a non-public (PRIKRAF603 financed) hospital, having signed a contract with the health insurance fund) are however taken into consideration as far as possible.604 The package of care605 as well as the share of costs606 to be borne by the patient can vary depending on the health insurance fund. In case of maternity and also for insured demonstrating a certain social level of need no cost sharing applies. In addition most of the patients have to pay a daily charge for inpatient care based on the Hospital Act. For elective interventions the consulting physician issues a referral/an admission notice. The patient can notify the doctor of special wishes, although (at least in the case of patients without supplementary private health insurance) the choice of hospital in which the patient is to be treated is ultimately dependant on the number of free beds. The referring physician can clarify with the hospital as to whether there is a free bed for his patient (this is considered a special service of the physician for his patient). The need for inpatient care is verified by the hospital upon admission of the patient. In theory a free choice of doctor is also possible in the private ward. This is however not legally stipulated. Private insurances use this in part to attract clients. In this case also, attempts are made to comply with the patient’s wishes as far as is possible. Free choice of doctor in the hospital is generally not advised since this would be difficult to arrange from an organizational point of view. This may be considered in some areas and may offer some advantages. Patients in the general ward of Austrian hospitals are not entitled to choose their personal physician. In so-called Belegspitäler, hospitals in which a doctor is permitted to supervise and treat his patient without being directly employed by that hospital, the patient is entitled to bring with him/her a trusted doctor to carry out the treatment or operation. The doctor pays a part of his fees to the hospital in exchange for the use of premises, apparatus und equipment.607 601 Brodil, W., Windisch-Graetz, M. (2005). Main features of Social Law. Vienna, WUV Universitätsverlag. Kind, M. (2005). My rights as a patient. Vienna, Verlag des Österreichischen Gewerkschaftsbundes GmbH. 603 PRIKRAF= Privatkrankenanstalten Finanzierungsfonds (Fund to finance the private hospitals) 604 General Social Security Act (Allgemeines Sozialversicherungsgesetz, ASVG) Kind, M. (2005). My rights as a patient. Vienna, Verlag des Österreichischen Gewerkschaftsbundes GmbH. 605 Hospitalisation in the private ward for insured according to the B-KUVG and the GSVG (those entitled to cash benefits) 606 No cost sharing following social insurance legislation on the general ward for insured according to the B-KUVG and the GSVG, cost sharing for insured according to the ASVG and the BSVG. 607 Hofmarcher and Rack 2006 602 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 189 Impacts of patient choice on equity and efficiency Due to the system of statutory social insurance most of the population has no choice of insurance fund. A consequence of this is that risk selection is very restricted if at all possible, resulting in more solidarity in the health system. Some insured of the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (Sozialversicherungsanstalt der gewerblichen Wirtschaft), namely free lance workers associated to a Chamber, based on § 5 GSVG) as well as voluntary insured persons have restricted options of choice. For the first group (e.g. doctors, vets, tax accountants) choice most likely applies to insured with a comparably higher income (potentially higher contributions) and a lower risk (assuming that higher education is correlated with a lower health risk), meaning that an exclusion from the insured population is, even if the group only represents 10% of the insured, not necessarily an advantage for the insurer. Persons choosing to take out voluntary insurance are people who do not meet criteria for statutory insurance, who are not covered as dependants and often have a lower income. Persons not covered by statutory social insurance, relying totally on private health insurance are not covered in this report. Insured pay social insurance contributions based on their income not on their risk. Contributions are progressive up to a certain income limit, at which they change to be regressive (high income earners pay a smaller proportion of their income for social insurance than low income earners). Social insurance is characterised by a re-distribution between the insured population, re-distributing between healthy and sick, between generations, between high-income earners and low-income earners, between insured without dependants and insured with dependants and partially also between men and women. Direct access to care is granted to insured by means of provision of benefits in kind. Some insured have changed their status voluntarily, paying for services in cash like private patients and applying for a refund afterwards. Health insurance funds display variations not only in connection with their benefits package but also with their tariffs. These are influenced by a range of factors, amongst others by legal or contractual provisions, by the negotiation power of the insurance fund and also by the financial situation of the fund. It should be considered if the fund is a regional fund or a national fund as the starting point at tariff negotiations is quite different. No information can be given on whether health care providers treat patients of different sickness funds in other ways or if risk selection takes place (motivated by differences in tariffs). In order to answer this question an empirical analysis ought to be performed. Regarding treatment in hospitals some insured persons are put at an advantage because the benefits package of their sickness fund includes treatment in the private ward (e.g. all insured according to the B-KUVG, certain groups of insured according to the GSVG – those utilising benefits in cash). User charges or exemptions may vary among insurance funds. However general exemptions from user charges exist like for instance for persons who are in need of social protection (based on a directive by the Hauptverband), for persons suffering from notifiable communicable diseases (by law) or for insured incurring high costs due to certain illnesses (by claim). This means that insured may be required to pay different user charges depending on the sickness fund they are registered with. Variations in the care of insured i.e. regarding the choice of health care providers and treatment may also be related to regional circumstances. Theoretically the insured can freely choose the doctor he consults, practically the density of physicians is considerably lower in rural areas than it is in urban areas. As a consequence the residence of the insured i.e. the place from which he accesses the health care provider can influence the type and scope of care provided. It should be noted however that not only the number of contract physicians, but also their availability (opening hours, working hours) have to be taken into consideration when assessing the extent of care provided. Access to emergency care in Austria is in line with international standards, for other types of care insured in rural areas may have to be prepared to travel longer distances. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 190 In addition to regional circumstances the socioeconomic status of individuals as well as their nationality (e.g. migrants), their religion or their physical or mental condition (disability) influences their care. A further aspect influencing the choice of health care provider is the information status of the insured i.e. a lack of information/knowledge results in the fact that the insured may consume either not the appropriate care or no care at all. Insured who are courageous enough to ask for information, who organise themselves in self-help-groups or who possess the means to facilitate information search (e.g. Internet) are put at an advantage. 7.4 Satisfaction with health care Another ‘output’ that could be examined is patient and public satisfaction. Data from a Eurobarometer survey and the European Social Survey both asked respondents a series of questions, of which some touched upon satisfaction with the health system. The results are discussed below. The European Social Survey provides a level of satisfaction ranked from 0 (least satisfied) to 8 (most satisfied). Austria ranks 5th out of the 25 EU member states, and considerably higher than the EU average (Figure 7.13). From the Eurobarometer survey, we can see that Austrians are especially satisfied with aspects of life where other Europeans are rather dissatisfied; that is, with law and order and the health care system. While 23.4% of Europeans are happy with law and order, 74.2% of Austrians are happy with it, and while 32.6% of EU citizens are happy with the health care system, 68.1% of Austrians are satisfied with their health care system. 42-52% of EU citizens are dissatisfied with these two aspects, but only 8-12% of Austrian citizens complain about these points. The education system and public transport garner a 55-57% satisfaction rate in Austria, and 14.4% and 19.8% dissatisfaction respectively. These satisfaction levels are also considerably higher than EU averages. Satisfaction and dissatisfaction levels with life in general are much closer to European averages with 85.1% of respondents in Austria saying that they are satisfied and 5.2% that they are dissatisfied. When people were asked what they consider to be 'the two most important issues facing [their country] at the moment' and were given a choice between 15 options (including an ‘open’ answer), 'crime' figured as the number one concern among Europeans (Figure 7.14). An average of 40.1% of EU citizens thought it was one of the two most important issues in their country, while ‘crime’ registered more support in Belgium, France, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands and the UK than any other answer. In second place, 'unemployment' was considered to be one of the two most important issues by roughly 1 in 3 Europeans (EU 15=35.9%), obtaining more support than any other issue in Germany, Greece, Spain, Austria and Finland. In third place, an average of 18.9% of EU citizens thought that the 'health care system' was one of the two most important issues, gathering more support than any other response in Sweden (52.1%), Portugal (38%) and Denmark (32.0%), and obtaining the second largest degree of support in the Netherlands (51.2%), the UK (40.2%), Ireland (38.9%) and Finland (38.8%). In Greece respondents indicated the 'health care system' as their third most important issue, with 26%. Conversely, the 'health care system' was ranked considerably lower in Italy (5th position), in Germany and Luxembourg (6th), Austria (7th), Belgium (9th), and France and Spain (11th place). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 191 Figure 7.11 Overall satisfaction with the health system (scale of 1-10) Belgium Luxembourg Finland Iceland Austria Denmark Switzerland France Spain Norway Slovakia Netherlands United Kingdom Czech EU Average Sweden Slovenia Greece Germany Estonia Ireland Portugal Hungary Poland Ukraine 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Source: European Social Survey 2004 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 192 Figure 7.12 Opinion on most important issue facing the country at the moment (15 options) Austria 7th Belgium 9th Immigration 3rd Denmark Finland 2nd France Greece 11th 3rd Germany 6th Italy Netherlands 5th 2nd Spain Sweden Te rrorism 11th Education UK 1st 2nd EU 15 3rd 0 10 20 30 40 % health care system 50 unemployment 60 70 crime Source: Eurobarometer survey 2002 Figure 7.13 Views on how the health system is run 15 EU U K ed en Sw Sp ai n s N et h er la nd Ita ly G re ec e an y er m G Fr an ce Fi nl an d ar k en m D el gi um B A us tr ia % 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Agree 1996 Agree 2002 Disagree 1996 Disagree 2002 Note: ‘Agree’: runs quite well / only minor changes; ‘Disagree’: only fundamental changes / needs to be rebuilt completely Source: Eurobarometer survey 2002 As seen in Figure 7.15, the majority of Austrians believe the health system runs quite well, although there was a slight decline from 1996 to 2002 (from about 72% to 68%). Only one country had a higher proportion of individuals agreeing with the statement – Finland. That same survey questioned the individuals about the extent to which doctors spent adequate time with them in general, and regarding preventive health and lifestyles; which is indicative of perceived quality of physician care. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 193 When asked whether they agree or not that 'doctors do not spend enough time with you when you go to them', respondents receive the opportunity to express how contented they are with the quality of the service which is given by their doctor (one of the most basic and ordinary health care services). The question targets a specific and common service, and is therefore very different from questions about satisfaction with the health care system as a whole. In general, Europeans agree that doctors do not spend enough time with them, as one in two EU citizens is of this opinion608, while one in three respondents disagrees.609 Dissatisfaction with the time doctors spend with patients is highest in Finland, Greece and Portugal, where around 60-65% of respondents agreed, while Greece had the highest percentage of ‘strongly agree’ answers (36.1%). Yet, citizens were more satisfied in the Netherlands, France and Sweden, as 35-40% of the public disagreed that doctors spend too little time with patients, while Denmark is the only country where an absolute majority (61.4%) disagreed that doctors do not spend enough time and the majority of respondents ‘strongly disagreed’ (34.7%). Another specific aspect of the doctor-patient relationship is dealt with when citizens are asked whether they agree or not that 'doctors do not spend enough time with you discussing preventive action and healthier lifestyle when you go to them' (Figure 7.16). A doctor’s role is not solely to cure illnesses and prescribe medicines, but also to give advice and information on healthier choices, and this question focuses on whether doctors are perceived to perform this role well enough. Taking the average across the fifteen countries, one in two respondents were dissatisfied610 with the amount of time doctors spend discussing prevention etc, while only one in four Europeans thought doctors spend enough time.611 Above 60% of citizens in Greece, Finland and Portugal agreed and were thus the most dissatisfied, with Greece being the only country where a majority of respondents, 40.7%, declared to ‘strongly agree’ that doctors spend too little time. On the other hand, around 30% of the Dutch, Austrian, Swedish and French respondents were satisfied with the time doctors spend on preventive information, while 46.6% of Danes were contented. Denmark is also the country with the highest rate of ‘strongly disagree’ at 22.9% (EU 15=8.6%). Figure 7.14 “Doctors do not spend enough time discussing prevention and lifestyle choices” 80 70 60 50 %40 30 20 10 15 EU K U ed en Sw Sp ai n s er la nd et h N G Ita ly an y er m re ec e G Fr an ce Fi nl an d ar k en m D el gi um B A us tr ia 0 Agree 2002 Source: Eurobarometer survey 2002 9, 11 Disagree 2002 Percentage of those who ‘strongly agree’ plus the percentage of those who ‘tend to agree’. Percentage of those who ‘tend to disagree’ plus the percentage of those who ‘strongly disagree’. 609, 12 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 194 7.4.1 Patient satisfaction in Austria When European Social Survey data are disaggregated to the regions in Austria, it appears there is very little variation within the countries (Figure 7.17). On the whole, health care is viewed as quite satisfactory. Figure 7.15 Satisfaction with health care in Austria – regional variation Vorarlberg Steiermark Burgenland Wien Average Oberösterreich Tirol Kärnten Niederösterreich Salzburg 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Source: European Social Survey 2004 The sample of 2256 Austrians aged above 15, who participated in the second round of the European Social Survey were included in a further analysis to investigate the factors significantly associated with satisfaction levels. A question asking people “what they think overall about the health services in Austria nowadays?” that measured satisfaction with health services on an 11-point scale (from extremely bad to extremely good) was the dependent variable. Explanatory variables included in the analysis are socio-demographic factors such as age (as a continuous variable), gender and legal marital status (married or not). Region consisted of the 9 states of Austria; Burgenland, Carinthia (Kärnten), Lower Austria (Niederösterreich), Upper Austria (Oberösterreich), Salzburg, Styria (Steiermark), Tyrol (Tirol), Vorarlberg and Vienna (Wien). Following the International Standard Classification of Occupation ISCO-88 occupation variable includes 9 categories: 1) legislators, senior officials, manager 2) professionals 3) technicians 4) clerks 5) service workers, shop and sales workers 6) skilled agricultural and fishery growers 7) craft workers 8) plant/machine operators and 9) elementary occupation. Subjective general health was reported on 5-point scale from very good to very bad, while income was reported on a subjective way asking people to report whether on the present household income they a) live comfortable, b) they cope, c) they find it difficult or d) they find it very difficult. Political preferences were measured by asking respondents which political party they voted in the last elections. Answers included: Social Democratic Party (SPÖ-socialists), Austrian People’s Party (ÖVPconservative), Freedom Party (FPÖ-conservative), Greens (Grüne-ecological), Liberals Forum (LIFliberal).612 612 Linear regression was run including the above explanatory variables in the model to predict satisfaction with health care. Preliminary analysis conducted on predictor variables to check for violations of the major assumptions of regression. Data has been weighted using: LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 195 Additional explanatory variables included a variable indicating whether the respondent had visited a doctor/GP/special the last 12 months (yes, no) and whether s/he feels s/he has enough choice regarding GP/specialist (yes, no). Finally, satisfaction with economic situation and trust in the legal system were both ranked on a 11-point scale and treated as a score. Table 7.4 shows regression coefficients from the regression analysis (including the political party voted). Model 1 (including political party voted) explains 35% (F(35,855) = 10.84, p = 0.00) of the variance in satisfaction with health services among Austrians. Table 7.4 Factors associated with satisfaction level in Austria Variable* Coefficient P Age Gender Marital status Feeling about income (base: living comfortable) coping difficult very difficult Region (base: Burgenland) Carinthia Lower Austria Upper Austria Salzburg Styria Tyrol Vorarlberg Vienna Occupation (base: legislators, managers) professionals technicians clerks service workers agricultural/fisher growers craft workers plant/machine operators elementary occupation Subjective general health (base: very good) good fair bad very bad Consulted doctor last 12 months Choice of doctor 0.013899 0.4327261 -0.3913699 0.013 0.012 0.018 -0.0659459 -0.635174 -0.0301027 0.683 0.036 0.966 -0.3791211 -0.4774587 -0.0680586 -1.264527 0.13379 0.2861942 0.313508 -0.0916177 0.364 0.113 0.844 0.004 0.686 0.42 0.416 0.779 0.0585152 -0.0418146 0.3112445 0.4093949 0.9167602 0.2756642 1.058077 0.1473994 0.855 0.909 0.337 0.262 0.089 0.469 0.021 0.7 -0.2398292 -0.507054 -1.131249 -0.8218153 -0.0767942 0.1139296 0.144 0.048 0.053 0.547 0.77 0.594 (1) Design weight, which corrects for differences in probability selection (i.e. makes the sample more representative of the “true” sample of individuals aged 15+ in the country) (2) Post-stratification weight, to adjust the sample data to conform more to the population’s parameters (in this case age and sex). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 196 Party voted last election (base: SPÖ) ÖVP FPÖ Grüne LIF Other Satisfaction with state of economy Trust in legal system _cons 0.5672335 0.5965118 0.000305 2.624297 2.201892 0.3186713 0.2015817 2.826877 0.004 0.053 0.999 0.042 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 * Dummy variables were as follows: Gender: 0=female, 1=male Marital Status: 0=not married, 1=married Consulted doctor last 12 months: 0=no, 1=yes (enough) choice re GP/doctor: 0=no 1=yes Note: Multicollinearity was not considered a concern since the strongest correlation between the independent variables was 0.36. Multicollinearity was also checked after the regression was run checking the variance inflation factors of the independent variables. The results confirmed that education and the variable indicating whether the respondent was hampered in daily life by any chronic illness were problematic and therefore were excluded from the final model. As shown in the above table, age and sex are both significant predictors of satisfaction with health services and so does marital status. Males and older people are more satisfied than females and younger people respectively (B=0.013, p<0.05; B=0.43, p<0.05), while being married is associated with lower rates of satisfaction (B=-0.39, p<0.05). Moreover, Austrians who find it difficult to cope on their present household income are significantly less satisfied with health services than those who live comfortably with their income (B=-0.64, p<0.05). Residents of Carinthia, Lower Austria, Upper Austria, Salzburg and Vienna seem less satisfied with heath services than those living in Burgenland (the reference region), but only Salzburg was significant at a 0.05 level. Plant and machine operators are the only occupation showing significant association with satisfaction (B=1.06, p<0.05) rating the services higher than the reference occupation, i.e. legislators, senior officials and managers. Self-reported health was also associated with satisfaction with health services. Unhealthier people rated the services lower than those reporting very good health condition, although this was significant only for those with fair health condition (B=-0.50, p<0.05). This is quite interesting given that unhealthier people are the ones using the health services more. However there was not enough evidence to support that access to health care (i.e. whether they have visited a doctor/GP/specialist at least once during the last 12 months) was significantly associated with satisfaction (although the regression coefficient has a negative sign). Political preferences were shown to be a very strong predictor of satisfaction with health services. In comparison to those who voted the Social Democratic Party of Austria (SPÖ), Austrian who voted People’s Party (ÖVP), the Liberal Forum (LIF) or reported voting another smaller party (other) rated the health services in the country higher (B = 0.57, p < 0.05; B = 2.62, p < 0.05; B = 2.20, p < 0.05, for ÖVP, LIF and other, respectively). Finally, satisfaction with the state of economy in the country as well as trust in the legal system were significant predictors of satisfaction with health services. Greater satisfaction with the state of economy (B=0.32, p<0.05) and increased trust in legal system (B=0.20, p<0.05) was associated with increased satisfaction with health services. Table 7.5 shows the regressions coefficients of the analysis including all the above explanatory variables used in the previous model but the party voted in the last elections. As shown in table 7.5, age, marital status and occupation are not significant anymore, while changes are observed in the region as well. On the LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 197 other hand, health becomes stronger predictor, while the rest variables behave more or less similarly to the previous model. Table 7.5 Factors associated with satisfaction (not including political preference) Variable* Coefficient P Age Gender Marital status Feeling about income (base: living comfortable) coping difficult very difficult Region (base: Burgenland) Carinthia Lower Austria Upper Austria Salzburg Styria Tyrol Vorarlberg Vienna Occupation (base: legislators, managers) professionals technicians clerks service workers agricultural/fisher growers craft workers plant/machine operators elementary occupation Subjective general health (base: very good) good fair bad very bad Consulted doctor last 12 months Choice of doctor Satisfaction with state of economy Trust in legel system _cons 0.0005429 0.3164862 -0.0733594 0.914 0.037 0.617 -0.085595 -0.5598244 -0.4584403 0.538 0.049 0.361 -0.0646398 -0.5924469 -0.1410001 -0.8446284 -0.0304646 -0.2685841 0.0071787 0.1430778 0.878 0.042 0.645 0.025 0.919 0.483 0.986 0.618 -0.3427133 -0.5569301 -0.4580064 -0.3097293 0.2588705 -0.1529969 -0.0199814 -0.0116312 0.237 0.092 0.132 0.33 0.589 0.631 0.955 0.974 -0.3376941 -0.1828786 -0.904571 -1.081605 -0.1166853 -0.2968684 0.3543473 0.1491528 4.882311 0.026 0.384 0.041 0.179 0.614 0.112 0.00 0.00 0.00 * Dummy variables was as follows: Gender: 0=female, 1=male Marital Status: 0=not married, 1=married Consulted doctor last 12 months: 0=no, 1=yes (enough) choice re GP/doctor: 0=no 1=yes LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 198 Note: Model 1 accounts for 35 percent (F(35,855) = 10.84, p = 0.00) of the variance in satisfaction with health services among individuals aged above 15 in Austria, while model 2 (excluding the political preferences) accounts for 25% (F(30,1657). This means the first model explains our dependent variable much better than the second. Satisfaction with the benefits package In the 1992 and 2002 Eurobarometer surveys, individuals across Europe were asked whether they felt the benefits packages should be reduced a ‘basic package’. While more individuals disagreed than agreed in most countries, there was a far wider discrepancy in some countries such as Sweden, Spain and the United Kingdom than other countries including Austria (Figure 7.18). Also, the extent to which individuals expect governments to fund all medical devices and technologies differs across countries (Figure 7.19); with more people agreeing in the tax-funded systems of Denmark, Finland, Sweden, and the United Kingdom than the rest. Figure 7.16 The provision of care should be restricted to a basic package, 1992 and 2002 Agree 1996 Agree 2002 Disagree 1996 15 EU UK Sp ai n Sw ed en Lu Ne x th er la nd s Po rt ug al y Ita l Au str ia Be lg iu m De nm ar k Fi nl an d Fr an ce G re ec e G er m an y Ir ela nd 90 80 70 60 50 % 40 30 20 10 0 Disagree 2 Source: Eurobarometer survey 2002 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 199 Figure 7.17 “It is impossible for any government/public/private health insurance scheme to pay for all new medical treatments and technology” 70 60 50 40 % 30 20 10 15 EU K U ed en Sw Sp ai n s er la nd Ita ly N et h an y G er m re ec e G Fr an ce Fi nl an d ar k en m D el gi um B A us tr ia 0 Agree 2002 Disagree 2002 Source: Eurobarometer survey 2002 7.5 Inter-generational solidarity: caring for older people It is interesting to compare the extent to which individuals believe family or the state should be paying for long-term care services for older people; an area also covered in the Eurobarometer survey. In terms of caring responsibilities, on average, a great majority of Europeans (85.9%) do not live with someone ill/ handicapped/ elderly whom they take care of and approximately the same percentage of EU citizens do not provide help to someone ill/ handicapped/ elderly not living with them. When asked who they think 'should mainly pay for taking care of elderly parents?' and were presented with four options – ‘the elderly parents themselves’, ‘their children’, ‘the national government or social insurance’ or ‘regional/ local government’ – the majority of Europeans (57.7%) answered that it should be the responsibility of the national government. In 14 countries this was the favoured option, receiving the highest levels of support in the Netherlands (74.4%), Finland (72.8%) and Greece (68.5%) (and East Germany – 75.5%), and the least support in Denmark, Spain and Ireland, where less than 50% of the public thought it was the national government’s responsibility. It should be noted, however, that the relatively low support in Denmark is compensated by the fact that 41.5% of Danes think the regional/ local government should pay for elderly care. This makes Denmark the country where the ‘public option’ is the most favoured, as 89.4% of the population believes that it is the national or local authorities’ responsibility to finance care for the elderly. The big exception to this trend is Austria, where only 25% of citizens thought that the national government/ social insurance should pay for the elderly while nearly 40% considered that ‘their children’ should pay. Other countries where the option of children paying for their elderly parents’ care received considerable support was Spain (32.4%) and Portugal (27.7%), in contrast to Denmark, Finland and the Netherlands where less than 5% of the population favoured this option (EU 15=14.2%). On average, 11.9% of Europeans thought ‘the elderly parents themselves’ should pay for the care they need. This option was particularly favoured in Germany (22.7%), Luxembourg (18.4%) and Austria (16.7%), but was very unpopular in Portugal, Sweden, Italy and Greece where only 5-6% of citizens believed that the elderly themselves should pay. Attitudes towards the ‘regional/ local option’ varied significantly as 41.5% of Danes and 26.9% of Italians supported it, but no-one in Sweden (0%) and only 1-2% in Germany and Portugal approved of it (EU 15=10.7%). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 200 8. CONTRIBUTION OF THE HEALTH SYSTEM TO HEALTH IMPROVEMENT 8.1 Trends in life expectancy in Europe As seen in the below figures, continual improvements in life expectancy are seen since 1975 in many European countries, namely in Western Europe (Figures 8.1 and 8.2). Disability-adjusted life expectancy is an estimate of the number of years a person will live in full health. This indicator was used in the World Health Report 2000 as the summary indicator of the level of population health status because it contains information about both mortality and morbidity. The prevalence of disability is required for its calculation, however, which could lead to comparability problems, since various countries use different definitions of disability. Figure 8.1 Life expectancy at birth in selected EU countries (males) 80 78 76 74 72 70 68 66 64 62 60 58 1975 AT ES 1980 FR SE 1985 1990 HU UK IT EU15 1995 LV EU10 2000 PL SK Figure 8.2 Life expectancy at birth in selected EU countries (females) 86 84 82 80 78 76 74 72 70 68 66 64 1975 AT ES 1980 FR SE 1985 1990 HU UK IT EU15 1995 LV EU10 2000 PL SK Source: WHO health for all data 2006 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 201 Table 8.1 Estimates of life expectancy and healthy life expectancy (HALE) in Europe, 2002 or most recent year (ranked by women) Healthy life expectancy Country Spain Sweden France Italy Germany Luxembourg Austria Finland Belgium Greece Netherlands Malta Slovenia United Kingdom Portugal Ireland Denmark Czech Republic Slovakia Estonia Cyprus Poland Hungary Lithuania Latvia Bulgaria Romania Turkey EU average EU-15 average NMS average Women 75.3 74.8 74.7 74.7 74 73.7 73.5 73.5 73.3 72.9 72.6 72.3 72.3 72.1 71.7 71.5 71.1 70.9 69.4 69 68.5 68.5 68.2 67.7 67.5 66.8 65.2 62.8 71.75 73.29 69.43 Life expectancy Men 69.9 71.9 69.3 70.7 69.6 69.3 69.3 68.7 68.9 69.1 69.7 69.7 66.6 69.1 66.7 68.1 68.6 65.9 63 59.2 66.7 63.1 61.5 58.9 58 62.5 61 61.2 66.86 69.26 63.26 Country Spain Italy France Sweden Finland Austria Germany Cyprus Greece Luxembourg Netherlands Malta Belgium United Kingdom Portugal Slovenia Ireland Denmark Poland Czech Republic Lithuania Slovakia Estonia Hungary Bulgaria Latvia Romania Turkey EU average EU-15 average NMS average Women 83.36 83.22 83.17 82.26 82.05 81.59 81.59 81.5 81.33 81.15 81.08 80.78 80.76 80.71 80.7 80.35 79.92 79.46 78.91 78.65 77.9 77.84 77.22 76.75 75.98 75.97 75.1 72.2 79.69 81.49 78.59 Men 76.41 77.11 75.64 77.85 75.25 76.03 75.69 77.25 76.57 74.94 76.36 76.33 74.23 76.08 73.82 72.6 74.56 75.05 70.53 72.09 66.51 69.91 66.18 68.39 68.97 65.73 67.71 67.9 73.06 75.706 70.55 Source: WHO health for all data 2006 While the advantage with indicators of healthy life expectancy and disability-adjusted (or disability-free) life expectancy is that they can be obtained for many countries and therefore compared613, they have an important weakness. HALE and DALE provide policy makers with little indication of the underlying factors that may be influencing health attainment in the country. These factors may include housing, education, transport and economic development, or the health system. 613 It should be noted, however, that adjusting life expectancy for levels of health involves a process of estimation, and in many countries, even life expectancy itself is estimated because of limited or absent data on mortality. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 202 8.2 Avoidable mortality Additionally, the use of DALYs as a measure health outcome has received considerable criticism, largely due to assumptions made in their calculations.614 In light of the controversy surrounding the use of disability-adjusted life expectancy, alternative methods of measuring health improvement have been suggested. These have the advantage of determining the extent to which the health system is contributing to health improvement, therefore serving as a tool to measure health system performance. Several approaches have been developed in attempts to quantify the contribution of the health system to health improvement. The most widely used to date makes use of readily available mortality data and makes assumptions about certain causes of death that should not occur in the presence of timely and effective medical intervention. This method has given rise to the development of numerous terms including “avoidable mortality” and “mortality amenable to health care”. Avoidable mortality as a concept was first developed by Rutstein and colleagues as a measure of quality of care in the 1970s.615 Since then this concept has been commented on, reviewed by and developed by several authors, most importantly, Holland, Charlton, Mackenbach and Westerling.616 More recently, Nolte and McKee updated the previous analysis using data from the 1980s and 1990s.617 Analyses of avoidable mortality are essentially based on a list of selected disease groups that are considered to be effectively treatable or preventable by health care services. This work has focused on differentiating the causes that are responsive to medical intervention through secondary prevention and treatment (‘treatable conditions’), and those responsive to interventions that are usually outside the direct control of the health services through inter-sectoral health policies (‘preventable’ conditions).618 614 For instance, in order to calculate the years of life lost to disease, age at death of people with disease was compared to a standard life expectancy as opposed to the actual life expectancy of the population group that is being studied A Williams, "Calculating the Global Burden of Disease: Time for a Strategic Re-Appraisal," Health Economics 8 (1999).. This practice causes significant distortions to international comparisons. Furthermore, an arbitrary gender gap was used to make the DALY calculations, which may underestimate the burden of disease of women relative to men. The method of calculating quality of life has also been widely criticized, mainly due to the use of ‘expert opinion’ and the practice of forced consistency of quality of life scores T Arnesen and E Nord, "The Value of Daly Life: Problems with Ethics and Validity of Disability Adjusted Life Years," BMJ 319, no. 7222 (1999).. Also, the use of age weights to account for the different social value of people at different ages is another ethical issue that has been widely argued. 615 D.D. Rutstein et al., "Measuring the Quality of Medical Care," New England Journal of Medicine 294 (1976). 616 J.R. Charlton et al., "Geographical Variation in Mortality from Conditions Amenable to Medical Intervention in England and Wales," Lancet i, no. 691-6 (1983), W.W Holland, ed., European Community Atlas of 'Avoidable Death', Commission of the European Communities Health Services Research Series No.3 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1988), W.W Holland, ed., European Community Atlas of 'Avoidable Death', 2nd ed., vol. 1, Commission of the European Communities Health Services Research Series No.6 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991), W.W Holland, ed., European Community Atlas of 'Avoidable Death', 2nd ed., vol. II, Commission of the European Communities Health Services Research Series No.9 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1993), W.W Holland, ed., European Community Atlas of 'Avoidable Death' 1985-89 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997), W.W Holland and E Breeze, "The Performance of Health Services" (paper presented at the The Political Economy of Health and Welfare: the twenty-second annual symposium of the Eugenics Society, London, 1985), W.W Holland et al., "Heaven Can Wait," Journal of Public Health Medicine 16 (1994), J.P Mackenbach, M.H Bouvier-Colle, and E. Jougla, ""Avoidable" Mortality and Health Services: A Review of Aggregate Data Studies," Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 44 (1990), R. Westerling, ""Avoidable" Causes of Death in Sweden 1974-85," Quality Assurance in Health Care 4 (1992). 617 E Nolte and M McKee, Does Healthcare Save Lives? Avoidable Mortality Revisited (London: The Nuffield Trust, 2004). 618 There are over 30 conditions considered treatable, some examples are: cancer of the colon, skin, cervix, testis and breast; diabetes mellitus; epilepsy; pneumonia; appendicitis; thyroid disease; measles. Three conditions are considered preventable: deaths from lung cancer, motor vehicle and traffic accidents and cirrhosis of the liver. It is important to note that over time the conditions that are considered treatable may change, therefore it is difficult to draw conclusions about time trends. However cross-country comparisons are not subject to the same methodological limitation, since at one point in time, the same standards in terms of quality of health care should apply to all countries. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 203 Improved access to timely and effective health care has a significant impact on health, in particular through reductions in infant mortality and in deaths among the middle aged and older people. Studies indicate that improvements in life expectancy can be attributed largely to improvements in mortality from amenable conditions, particularly during the 1980s619. These improvements in most countries resulted from falling infant mortality. However, falling mortality among the middle-aged was the main driver of improved amenable mortality in Denmark, the Netherlands, the UK, France (men) and Sweden (women). In the 1990s, while amenable mortality remained an important contributor to improvements in life expectancy in southern Europe (especially Portugal and Greece), its contribution to improvement in health in other countries was less significant, although still accounted for 20% of the total improvement among women. A recent comprehensive study of avoidable mortality in Europe uses data extracted from the World Health Organization (WHO) mortality files for the period 1990-2002.620 Levels and trends in avoidable mortality are examined by calculating age-standardized death rates with direct standardization to the European standard population. This analysis is restricted to the larger countries of the EU, thus excluding Malta and Luxembourg, and also limited to those with sufficient data for the time period, thus excluding Cyprus, Turkey, Belgium, Slovakia, Denmark and Greece. Treatable mortality As shown in Figure 33, treatable mortality was highest in central and eastern European countries (particularly Romania, Bulgaria and Hungary) in both 1990/91 and 2000/02. Portugal is the only EU 15 country to display similarly high levels. Levels were lowest in France (women) and Sweden (men). All countries, except Romania (men), experienced declines in treatable mortality during the 1990s, particularly Portugal, Austria and Finland as well as new EU member states (in Czech Republic, rates declined by around one-third). Figure 8.3 Age-standardized death rates of treatable mortality in 18 European countries, 1990/91 and 2000/02 Treatable Mortality: Men Treatable Mortality: Women Romania Bulgaria Hungary Latvia Estonia Czech Republic Poland Portugal Lithuania Slovenia Austria Finland Ireland Germany UK Italy Spain France Netherlands Sweden 1990/91 2000/01/02 0 50 100 150 200 250 Deaths/ 100 000 population Romania Bulgaria Hungary Latvia Estonia Czech Republic Poland Lithuania Portugal Slovenia UK Ireland Austria Germany Finland Italy Netherlands Spain Sweden France 1990/01 2000/01/02 0 50 100 150 200 250 Deaths/ 100 000 Source: Nolte and McKee 2004 619 Nolte and McKee, Does Healthcare Save Lives? Avoidable Mortality Revisited. C. Newey et al., "Avoidable Mortality in the Enlarged European Union," (Paris: Institut des Sciences de la Santé, 2003). 620 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 204 Preventable mortality Preventable mortality estimates combine three major causes: deaths from lung cancer, motor vehicle and traffic accidents and cirrhosis of the liver. There is a substantial gap between rates of preventable mortality for men and women in all countries, with death rates among men at least twice those of women (Figure 8.4). This gender gap in preventable mortality is most pronounced in the new Member States of central and Eastern Europe, which also show the highest absolute values, especially for Hungarian men. This gap reflects the much greater exposure to risks such as drinking and smoking among men. For women, death rates were again highest in Hungary, followed at some distance by Slovenia and Romania, as well as the United Kingdom. Unlike the situation with treatable causes, throughout the 1990s men have consistently seen declines in preventable mortality whilst women have not. The declines among men were most prominent in Italy, Austria, Portugal, Finland, the United Kingdom Czech Republic and Slovenia. Preventable mortality among women declined in some countries, particularly those in the Mediterranean region, and increased in Sweden and the Netherlands and all new member states (except Slovenia) and Romania. By 2000/2002, levels of preventable mortality among women were lowest in Spain and Portugal, as well as Bulgaria. Figure 8.4 Age-standardized death rates of preventable mortality in 18 European countries, 1990/91 and 2000/02 Preventable Mortality: Women Preventable Mortality: Men Hungary Slovenia Latvia Estonia Czech Poland Lithuania Romania Italy Austria Portugal Spain France Germany Bulgaria Netherlands Finland UK Ireland Sweden Hungary Slovenia Romania UK Austria Ireland Portugal Germany Czech Italy Poland France Estonia Latvia Lithuania Sweden Netherla Spain Finland Bulgaria 1990/01 2000/01/02 0 50 100 150 200 250 Deaths/ 100 000 1990/91 2000/01/02 0 20 40 60 Deaths/ 100 000 Source: Nolte and McKee 2004 In Austria, improvements in avoidable mortality made significant positive contributions to the overall increase in life expectancy in the 1980s, accounting for 40-44% of the increase in mean and women. About one-fifth of the improvement resulted from a decline in infant mortality, and another 13-16% due to declining adult (40+) mortality. In the 1990s, avoidable mortality changes made a smaller contributions to life expectancy than in the 1980s, especially among men. Unlike the 1980s, much of the improvement in life expectancy can be attributed to falling mortality among the middle-aged. However among women, avoidable deaths still accounted for almost 40% of the increase in life expectancy. What causes premature deaths? The overall trends in avoidable mortality obscure important differences in specific categories of causes of deaths. Therefore, what are the causes of premature deaths? This section examines three of the main causes LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 205 of treatable deaths: infant mortality, cerebrovascular disease, and testicular cancer; and the three main causes of preventable deaths: tobacco smoking, road traffic accidents, and alcohol consumption. Infant mortality reflects deficiencies in the health system, in particular prenatal and natal care, as well as broader determinants such as living conditions. Infant mortality has decreased in the EU-15 in the last 25-30 years because of improvements in these two areas. Likewise, infant and child mortality rates have been falling since the 1980s, and accelerated in the 1990s, in all the new Members States and in particular in the three Baltic countries and Poland. The reduction in infant mortality in the central European countries almost immediately following transition explains the improvement in treatable mortality observed in these countries. However the countries with less improvement in treatable mortality over the 1990s experienced increases in infant mortality, which were short-lived in some (Estonia, Lithuania) and sustained in others (Latvia, Bulgaria). Many countries in Europe also experienced declines in mortality from cerebrovascular disease throughout the 1990s, which again were immediate in some (Czech Republic, Slovakia, Slovenia, Hungarian women) while temporarily increasing in others, particularly the Baltic states of Estonia and Latvia, as well as Bulgaria and Romania. Hypertension is a strong risk factor for cerebrovascular disease, and its control was shown to be particularly poor in Eastern Europe.621 However, this is now changing, with recent improvements in cerebrovascular disease mortality possibly reflecting a combination of better access to pharmaceuticals and hypertensive treatment along with improvements in specialized health care. Despite evidence of greater awareness and significant declines in the prevalence of hypertension in the new Member States622, it is noted that the treatment of hypertension is still largely inadequate, with low proportions of blood pressure control reported in a number of countries, including Latvia and Poland.623 Indeed, levels of premature mortality from cerebrovascular disease in the new Member States and Candidate Countries are still substantially higher than in the EU15. Tobacco smoking, diet (salt intake), and alcohol, are additional important risk factors for cerebrovascular disease. Death from testicular cancer is a clear indication of shortcomings in the health system, since it is a type of cancer that can be treated effectively. Romania and Bulgaria, whose levels of mortality from treatable conditions were the highest, were also the only countries to have recorded an increase in mortality from testicular cancer among men over the last 30 years, at a time when substantial improvements had occurred in the rest of Europe due in part to improved diagnosis.624 Tobacco smoking is the single most important risk factor of lung cancer; and lung cancer is the single most preventable disease. Tobacco smoking is also a significant risk factor for other common diseases such as coronary heart disease. Traditionally smoking has been very common among men throughout Europe, and less so amongst women. As a consequence, a gender gap in death rates from lung cancer has emerged. Female smoking patterns have however been changing with smoking rates increasing625, especially among the young in major cities.626 This change is reflected in the increases in preventable mortality seen for countries such as Hungary, Romania and Slovenia, and Sweden and the Netherlands627, where lung cancer 621 D. Ryglewicz et al., "Stroke Mortality Rates in Poland Did Not Decline between 1984 and 1992," Stroke 28 (1998). R. Cifkova et al., "Trends in Blood Pressure Levels, Prevalence, Awareness, Treatment, and Control of Hypertension in the Czech Population from 1985 to 2000/01," J Hypertens 22 (2004). 623 V. Dzerve, N. Britcina, and J. Pakhomova, "Prevalence and Control of Hypertension in Latvia," J Hum Hypertens 18 (2004), S.L. Rywik et al., "Poland and U.S. Collaborative Study on Cardiovascular Epidemiology in the Community: Prevalence, Awareness, Treatment, and Control of Hypertension in the Pol-Monica Project and the U.S. Atherosclerosis Risk in Communities Study," Ann Epidemiol 8 (1998). 622 624 F. Levi et al., "Western and Eastern European Trends in Testicular Cancer Mortality," Lancet 357 (2001). 625 F. Levi et al., "Trends in Mortality from Major Cancers in the European Union, Including Acceding Countries, in 2004," Cancer 101, no. 12 (2004), J.E. Tyczynski et al., "Lung Cancer Mortality Patterns in Selected Central, Eastern and Southern European Countries," Int J Cancer 109 (2004). 626 B. Forey et al., International Smoking Statistics. Second Edition (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002). 627 Among women the Netherlands has the highest prevalence of smoking (almost 30%) next to Greece in the EU15. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 206 rates for women have risen over the last decade, to a large extent, reflecting the increasing death toll among a generation of women who began smoking in the 1960s. It has been predicted that this increase in smoking will surpass trends already seen in several countries in Western Europe.628 However, as seen in Poland, the negative impact of transition on tobacco consumption does not have to be definitive. The Polish government was the first in the region to enact comprehensive tobacco control legislation and, since 1995, has developed a set of tobacco control policies that were more comprehensive than those in force in the EU15.629 Smoking rates are now declining in this country with health indicators improving as a result. In 1996 54% of Polish men smoked, but by 2003 this had fallen to 39%.630 It is anticipated that the gender gap in preventable mortality, as defined here, will continue to narrow in the foreseeable future, reflecting the changing patterns in smoking. The consistent decline in mortality from traffic accidents during the 1990s has contributed greatly to the declines in preventable mortality seen for men, particularly in the Mediterranean countries. It has also had a major influence on rates of preventable mortality for women, outweighing the effects of increasing rates of lung cancer and liver cirrhosis for women in countries such as Finland. Liver cirrhosis, a condition that is strongly related to alcohol consumption631, also appears to be a growing concern for a number of countries, particularly Romania, the Baltic states, Ireland and United Kingdom, where rates have considerably increased for both men and women. National statistics data from England and Wales show the increase in alcohol-related deaths since 1980. WHO Regional Office for Europe recently grouped countries into levels of alcohol consumed. High consuming countries632 were found to be: Czech Republic, France, Germany, Ireland, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Portugal, Slovenia and Spain, and Denmark, Greece, Hungary, and Latvia.633 Avoidable mortality vs. DALYs As shown in the figure below, the ranking for 19 countries based on disability-adjusted life expectancy (as calculated by the WHO) is significantly different from the ranking with amenable mortality. In using avoidable mortality to create the ranking, significant losses in rank are seen in Greece (7 to 12) and the UK (10 to 18), while gains are seen in Denmark (17-10), Finland (13 to 8), Germany (14-6) and Norway (11 to 2). 628 P. Brennan and I. Bray, "Recent Trends and Future Directions for Lung Cancer Mortality in Europe," Br J Cancer 87 (2002). 629 A.B. Gilmore et al., "Free Trade Versus the Protection of Public Health: The Examples of Aclohol and Tobacco.," in Health Policy and European Union Enlargement, ed. M. McKee, L. MacLehose, and E. Nolte (Buckingham: Open University Press, 2004). 630 European Commission, "Tobacco or Health in the European Union: Past, Present and Future," (Brussels: European Commission, DG Health and Consumer Protection, 2004). 631 G. Corrao et al., "A Meta-Analysis of Alcohol Consumption and the Risk of 15 Diseases," Prev Med 38, no. 5 (2004). 632 More than 10 litres per person per year 633 N. Rehn, R Room, and G Edwards, "Alcohol in the European Region – Consumption, Harm and Policies," (Copenhagen: World Health Organization Regional Office for Europe, 2001). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 207 Figure 8.5 Comparison of rankings based on disability adjusted life expectancy (1999) and standardized death rates (per 100,000; ages 0-74) from mortality amenable to health care (1988) Source: Nolte and McKee, 2003 8.3 Trends in chronic diseases in Europe In Europe, obesity rates range between 9.5 and 27% among men and reach 35% among women634 (Figure 8.6). Central and Eastern European countries have experienced a dramatic increase in obesity rates in the last decade.635 In Hungary, the obesity rate has doubled since 1989. Four-fifths of Latvian women and Czech men have a body mass index greater than 25, therefore are classified as overweight. Compared to the EU average, the prevalence of obesity, particularly among women, is significantly higher in Greece, Malta and Cyprus. An important cause of obesity has been the arrival of fast food and the decrease in physical activity in these countries where the traditional diet is based on meat, fat and non-vegetables. Tobacco smoking is the single most important risk factor of lung cancer; and lung cancer is the single most preventable disease. Tobacco use continues to be the largest single cause of death and disease in the EU killing over 650,000 people every year. Beyond the direct effects to the user, tobacco smoke is a serious environmental health hazard; current estimates indicate that approximately 100,000 non-smoking Europeans die each year due to second-hand smoke. If current smoking patterns continue, it will likely cause nearly 10 million deaths each year by 2020.636 In addition to the public health impacts, the EU bears a substantial economic burden due to smoking. Conservative estimates project the costs of tobacco use to range between €98-130 billion a year or 1.04-1.39% of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for 2000. Tobacco smoking is also a significant risk factor for other common diseases such as coronary heart disease. Traditionally smoking has been very common among men throughout Europe, and less so amongst women. As a consequence, a gender gap in death rates from lung cancer has emerged. Female smoking patterns 634 It is important to highlight the difficulties in drawing comparisons across countries in obesity, due to potential differences in measurement and lack of standardized methodology. 635 D.A. Spritzer, "Obesity Epidemic Migrates East," Canadian Medical Association Journal 171, no. 10 (2004). C Murray and A.D Lopez, eds., The Global Burden of Disease: A Comprehensive Assessment of Mortality and Disability from Diseases, Injuries and Risk Factors in 1990 and Projected to 2020 (Cambridge, US: Harvard School of Public Health Care, 1996). 636 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 208 have however been changing with smoking rates increasing637, especially among the young in major cities.638 This change is reflected in the increases in preventable mortality seen for countries such as Hungary, Romania and Slovenia, and Sweden and the Netherlands639, where lung cancer rates for women have risen over the last decade, to a large extent, reflecting the increasing death toll among a generation of women who began smoking in the 1960s. It has been predicted that this increase in smoking will surpass trends already seen in several countries in Western Europe.640 Smoking rates are incredibly high in the countries of CEE.641 For example, the prevalence of smoking among the Turkish, Hungarian, Latvian and Bulgarian male and female population is over 65% (See Figure 8.7). In Malta, tobacco consumption was 68% higher than the EU average in 1999.642 Since 2000, expenditure on tobacco, alcohol and other narcotics has been reduced in Malta but has continued to increase in Cyprus. While the policy response to tobacco was initially weak, more recently several countries, particularly Poland, Hungary and the Baltic States, have enacted tobacco programs that are stronger than in many EU countries.643 Figure 8.6 Obesity prevalence in Europe 40 Male, BMI >30 Female, BMI >30 Prevalence obesity 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 IT Nl FR DK SE PL BE SI LU AT EE ES IE LV LT SK FI HU UK DE CY PT CZ MT EL Source: International Obesity Task Force, 2005 Although the vast majority of tobacco-related death and disability occurs in middle-aged and older adults, smoking behaviour is most commonly established in childhood and adolescence. In fact, the vast majority of smokers begin using tobacco products well in advance of 18 years old.644 Young smokers may acquire the habit and become addicted prior to adulthood, rendering it difficult to quit and increasing the risk for tobacco-related health problems later in life. It has been estimated that unless current trends change, 30 to 40% of the approximately 2.3 billion children and teenagers worldwide will become smokers in early adult 637 Levi et al., "Trends in Mortality from Major Cancers in the European Union, Including Acceding Countries, in 2004.", Tyczynski et al., "Lung Cancer Mortality Patterns in Selected Central, Eastern and Southern European Countries." 638 Forey et al., International Smoking Statistics. Second Edition. 639 Among women the Netherlands has the highest prevalence of smoking (almost 30%) next to Greece in the EU15. 640 Brennan and Bray, "Recent Trends and Future Directions for Lung Cancer Mortality in Europe." 641 I. Pudule et al., "Patterns of Smoking in the Baltic Republics," Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 53 (1999). 642 World Health Organization Regional Office for Europe, "Health for All Database," (Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe,, 2005). 643 K. Fagerstrom et al., "The Anti-Smoking Climate in Eu Countries and Poland," Lung Cancer 32 (2001). 644 US Department of Health and Human Services, "Preventing Tobacco Use among Young People: A Report of the Surgeon General," (Atlanta, Georgia: Public Health Service, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Office on Smoking and Health, 1994). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 209 life and beyond.645 Pierce and Gilpin found that half of all new male adolescent smokers will smoke for at least 16 years, while females continue the habit for 20 years.646 Figure 8.7 Regular daily smokers in the adult population (age 15+), 2003 LV TR EL EE BG LT SK H PL ES DE NL PT R CZ IT DK BE FR MT AT CY IE SI UK FI SE Female male 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 Source: WHO Health for All, 2006 The reasons for tobacco use among youth are vast and complex, but predominately relate to the behaviour, attitudes, and expectations of parents, peers, and broader society. Young people are more likely to become smokers if they have parents, older siblings, and/or friends who smoke.647 Other determinants for youth tobacco use include cultural and religious norms, availability of tobacco products, tobacco control policies and strategies (e.g., pricing of cigarettes), and tobacco advertising, promotion, and marketing efforts. Increasingly, tobacco advertising and promotional activities are playing a role in the onset of smoking in children and adolescents, especially considering the multitude of new indirect marketing channels that are used to target children, such as sponsoring sporting events and branding merchandise (e.g., clothing, toys). In fact, studies have shown that exposure to cigarette advertising is predictive of smoking among youth.648 645 R. Peto et al., "Mortality from Smoking Worldwide," British Medical Bulletin 52 (1996). J.P. Pierce and E. Gilpin, "How Long Will Today's New Adolescent Smoker Be Addicted to Cigarettes?," American Journal of Public Health 86, no. 2 (1996). 647 J.R. Eiser et al., "Adolescent Smoking: Attitudes, Norms and Parental Influence," British Journal of Social Psychology 28 (1989), S.L. Tyas and L.L. Pederson, "Psychosocial Factors Related to Adolescent Smoking: A Critical Review of the Literature," Tobacco Control 7 (1998). 648 N. Evans and A. Farkas, "Influence of Tobacco Marketing and Exposure to Smokers on Adolescent Susceptibility to Smoking," Journal of the National Cancer Institute 87, no. 20 (1995). 646 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 210 According to the 2000-2001 HBSC survey, the proportion of young people in the EU who has ever smoked649 rises significantly with age, from 15% for 11-year-olds to 40% for 13-year-olds and 62% for 15year-olds. The increase in the proportion of children who ever smoked is most significant between 11 and 13 years of age, where half of all countries had rates at least three times higher for 13-year-olds than for 11year-olds.650 The proportion of children who ever smoked across all age groups was highest in Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, and the UK, while Greece and Malta had a lower percentage of tobacco use. There are also gender differences in the prevalence of smoking among youth. Among younger children, rates of smoking are substantially higher for boys than for girls in almost all countries. However, with increased age, more girls than boys have smoked, with differences being particularly marked in Scotland and Wales. In terms of smoking frequency, 84% of young people (average of all age groups) do not currently smoke.651 Across all countries, approximately one third of those who smoke do so less than once a week (5%), with the other two thirds (11%) smoking at least once a week.652 The remaining 7% (approximately half of all smokers) smoke daily. Again, weekly and daily smoking rates increase substantially with age and gender. The percentage of children who smoke daily increases from an average of 1% among 11-year olds, to 5% among the 13-year olds, and it reaches 18% in the oldest age group (Table 8.2). Among the youngest children, daily smoking habit is highest in Hungary, England and Portugal; while in Sweden, the Netherlands, and Denmark either no children or less than 0.2% smoked daily among this age group. Gender differences are similar to those emphasised previously, among 15-year-olds, girls tend to smoke more than boys in half of the countries, particularly in Northern and Western Europe. Table 8.2 Percentage of young people aged 11, 13, and 15 years old who smoke every day 11-year-olds 13-year-olds 15-year-olds Austria Belgium (Flemish) Belgium (French) Czech Republic Denmark England Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Latvia Lithuania Malta Netherlands Poland Boys (%) 0.9 0.3 0.7 1.3 0.0 1.5 1.5 0.3 0.8 1.5 0.8 2.4 0.8 0.6 0.5 1.2 0.8 0.0 1.2 Girls (%) 0.4 0.1 0.0 0.3 0.2 0.9 0.3 0.1 0.4 1.3 0.0 0.6 0.6 0.0 0.3 0.5 0.0 0.1 0.1 Boys (%) 3.3 4.5 3.3 6.2 3.0 6.9 7.6 6.6 3.5 10.2 2.7 5.5 2.5 3.4 8.8 6.2 4.1 3.5 7.5 Girls (%) 2.4 3.3 3.3 4.1 2.8 8.9 3.9 6.1 3.2 10.1 1.4 2.8 5.7 2.6 2.5 3.6 5.8 5.7 4.0 Boys (%) 19.5 18.3 16.0 20.2 13.7 15.8 23.3 22.1 19.5 26.3 9.2 20.7 14.6 16.1 21.8 26.6 8.6 18.7 21.4 Girls (%) 24.8 19.1 20.3 22.9 15.8 19.6 11.6 23.3 20.1 28.7 10.6 18.0 16.5 16.1 14.4 11.2 8.4 19.7 11.6 649 This proportion includes a wide range of people, including those who just experimented, those who become regular smokers and even those who smoked in the past but now have stopped. 650 World Health Organization, "Young People's Health in Context. Health Behaviour in School-Aged Children (Hsbc)Study: International Report from the 2001/2002 Survey. Health Policy for Children and Adolescent, No.4.," (Geneva: World Health Organization, 2004). 651 Children were asked how often they smoke tobacco at present. Responses categories were: ‘I don’t smoke’, ‘Every day’, ‘At least once a week but not every day’, ‘Less than once a week’. 652 World Health Organization, "Young People's Health in Context. Health Behaviour in School-Aged Children (Hsbc)Study: International Report from the 2001/2002 Survey. Health Policy for Children and Adolescent, No.4.." LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 211 1.4 Portugal 0.8 Scotland 1.1 Slovenia 0.9 Spain 0.0 Sweden 0.9 Wales Source: HSBC, 2000-2001. 1.0 8.0 5.3 13.1 19.5 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.0 0.9 2.7 3.5 5.0 2.8 6.0 5.8 1.8 3.8 3.9 11.9 13.0 22.5 16.6 5.7 12.1 19.2 23.2 23.2 13.8 21.5 Lung cancer is the most common cancer in Europe, nearly 400,000 new cases per year.653 As Figure 8.8 shows, age-standardized incidence rates are markedly higher in the east than in the west. Hungary has the highest rates of male lung cancer in Europe and in the world, followed in Europe by Belgium. The lowest rates for men are observed in Sweden and Portugal. For women, the highest rates are registered in Denmark, Hungary and the United Kingdom; while, the lowest incidence rates are found in Spain, Malta and Portugal. Male death rates for lung cancer are now decreasing in most European countries included the new Member States. On the contrary, mortality for lung cancer among women is increasing almost everywhere, but the UK and to same extent Ireland and Denmark654. The leading contributors of lung cancer are the number of cigarettes smoked per day, the degree of inhalation and the initial age of smoking.655 The relative risk of developing lung cancer is 20-30 times higher for smokers than for non-smokers. Cervical cancer is also relatively common among the new Member States, reflecting high rates of sexually transmitted diseases, infrequent use of barrier contraceptives, and ineffective, mostly opportunistic screening. 656 Figure 8.8 Cancer incidence per 100,000, 2003 or latest year available HU CZ DK IE SE DK FR UK SI FI EE AT NL LT MT SK BE LV BG PT PL RO CY 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 Source: WHO Health for All, 2006 653 J.E. Tyczynski, F. Bray, and D.M. Parkin, "Lung Cancer in Europe. European Network of Cancer Registries (Encr), Vol.1," (International Agency for Research on Cancer, 2002). 654 J. Didkowska et al., "Lung Cancer Mortality at Age 35-54 in the European Union: Ecological Study of Evolving Tobacco Epidemics," British Medical Journal 331 (2005). 655 Ibid, Tyczynski, Bray, and Parkin, "Lung Cancer in Europe. European Network of Cancer Registries (Encr), Vol.1." 656 F. Levi et al., "Cervical Cancer Mortality in Young Women in Europe: Patterns and Trends," European Journal of Cancer 36 (2000). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 212 Figure 8.9 Age-standardized lung cancer incidence rates / 100,000 population in Europe, 2003 HU PL BE EE CZ SK SI NL LV LU IT LT EL FR ES RO DE BG UK DK MT AT IE FI PT SE ASR female ASR male 0 20 40 60 80 100 Source: Tyczynski, Bray et al 2004 Cancer survival rates In Europe, 35% of men and 50% of women diagnosed in the late 1980s with any cancer (excluding nonmelanoma skin cancer) survived at least five years after diagnosis. For most cancers, however, five-year survival does not mean cure: even 10 years after diagnosis, there is still some excess mortality due to cancer. At present, more than one third of European patients are cured of their cancer.657 In general, survival is markedly lower in eastern European countries than in Western Europe. However, in western Europe there is still room for improvement. For many cancer sites, especially those for which early diagnosis is a major determinant of favourable prognosis, survival was higher in northern countries (Finland, Iceland, Sweden), intermediate in continental Europe (Austria, France, Germany, Italy, The Netherlands, Spain and Switzerland), and lower in Denmark and the UK. The highest survival rates were usually recorded in Iceland, Sweden (South Sweden cancer registry), Switzerland (Geneva and Basel cancer registries) or The Netherlands (Eindhoven cancer registry). The survival of patients with melanoma was higher in Nordic countries and the UK than in southern European countries. With a few exceptions, survival increased in all these countries but this pattern of differences persisted. By 1989, the survival differences between continental and northern European countries were diminishing for colorectal and breast cancer, melanoma of the skin and Hodgkin's disease. Comparison of the geographical variation with demographic, sociological and health economic indicators shows that in general, cancer patients' survival is higher where overall life-expectancy is higher. Significant factors associated with better survival rates include: proportion of GDP spent on health, level of 657 International Agency for Research on Cancer, Cancer Survival in Europe (1999 [cited July 21 2006]); available from http://www.iarc.fr/ENG/Press_Releases/archives/pr129a.html. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 213 employment, number of hospital beds and number of CT scanners per million population. Within Western Europe, these factors appear to be responsible for over 70% of the inter-country variability of survival for prostate cancer, 65% for breast, 60% for rectum and 50% for stomach cancer. Socio-economic differences may be explaining some of the within-country variation, as has been shown in the United Kingdom. 8.4 Screening programs Screening can be defined as: a public health service in which members of a defined population, who do not necessarily perceive they are at risk of, or are already affected by, a disease or its complications, are asked a question or offered a test to identify those individuals who are more likely to be helped than harmed by further tests or treatment to reduce the risk of disease or its complications. The basic criteria to be fulfilled before screening for any condition is introduced have been stated clearly over many years. They are fundamental to the integrity of the screening process in any country. They are reproduced in full on the UK National Screening Committee’s website,4 and are summarised in Table 8.3.658 Table 8.3 Summary of criteria for screening Category Criteria Condition The condition sought should be an important health problem whose natural history, including development from latent to declared disease is adequately understood. The condition should have a recognisable latent or early symptomatic stage. There should be a suitable diagnostic test that is available, safe and acceptable to the population concerned. There should be an agreed policy, based on respectable test findings and national standards, as to whom to regard as patients, and the whole process should be a continuing one There should be an accepted and established treatment or intervention for individuals identified as having the disease or pre-disease condition and facilities for treatment should be available. The cost of case-finding (including diagnosis and treatment) should be economically balanced in relation to possible expenditure on medical care as a whole. Diagnosis Treatment Cost Source: Holland et al 2006 Screening in adults is potentially big business. Media interest in health is insatiable and anyone who reads the newspapers, watches television or listens to radio can hardly fail to be aware of the various diseases that may be lying in wait for them. Above all, before any further national screening program is introduced, it must be clear that the long established screening criteria are satisfied and the evidence base exists. 658 W.W Holland, S Stewart, and C Masseria, Screening in Europe: A Policy Brief (Copenhagen: WHO on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2006). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 214 Table 8.4 Recommendations for screening in adults Condition Comment Breast cancer National program should be continued but kept under close review with emphasis on quality control, staff training and good information. Cervical cancer National program should be continued with review of alternative types of tests and of age range of those eligible and frequency of screening. Good information to be a priority. Colorectal cancer National screening program by faecal occult blood testing for adults aged 50-74 years. Abdominal aortic Ultrasound screening of men aged 65 and over seems a reasonable aneurysm proposition provided the necessary resources are in place. Diabetic retinopathy National program of screening for all diabetics aged over 12. It is essential to be quite clear about how, when and where screening should happen to ensure effective implementation. Risk factors for Surveillance/case-finding approach in primary care CHD/Stroke Blood pressure Cholesterol Smoking cessation Weight Source: Holland et al 2006 Breast and cervical cancer The national programs for breast and cervical cancer should be continued but kept under review with an emphasis on quality control and balanced understandable information to enable women to make a truly informed choice without pressure from health professionals on whether or not to participate. Efforts must also be made to improve coverage of those at highest risk. A national program of screening for colorectal cancer by faecal occult blood testing in adults aged from 50 to 74 years has been agreed in the UK but it is essential that adequate diagnostic, treatment and follow-up facilities are in place before it is introduced. Based on the directives developed by Europe Against Cancer, the Belgian Communities and the Federal Government signed, in October 2000, a protocol to organise and finance a national campaign of breast cancer screening for women between 50 and 69 years old. The responsibility for the coordination of the campaign rests with 11 recognised screening centres. There are five centres in Wallonia (one per province), five in Flanders (in the four Flemish universities and in Bruges) and one in Brussels. The screening centres are responsible for making information available to the target group, sending out the invitations, re-testing where necessary, recording of data and reporting to the referring doctor. In Flanders the campaign started on 15 June 2001 and in Wallonia and Brussels a year later. A program of cervical cancer screening has been running since 1994 in Belgium when the Flemish Government decided to reorient the organization of secondary prevention of cervical cancer according to the European guidelines. The program targets women aged between 25 and 64 years, who are invited for a Pap smear every three years. The program is administered and evaluated by the Scientific Institute of Public Health in collaboration with the Communities. Despite the scientific support, no formal screening program is organised in the French Community. Screening programs for breast cancer are established in two of the 14 Danish county councils (Funen and H:S) for women aged 50-69 years. These two screening programs cover 20% of the target Danish population. Screening for cervical cancer has recently been made available in all 14 Danish county councils. Women in the age group 23-59 years are invited to participate, except in Copenhagen, where coverage is limited to women aged 25-45 years. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 215 In Finland, under the terms of the Public Health Act, women between the ages of 50 and 59 years are invited every two years for breast screening. In Finland, the Public Health Act states that women aged 3060 years old should be invited for screening for cervical cancer every five years. In France, screening for breast cancer, previously limited to some départements (32 at the end of 2002), has been extended since January 2004. Every woman between 50 and 74 years (except for those in Guyana) is invited for a free breast screening every two years. A strategic objective of the Public Health Act (August, 2004) is to ‘reduce the percentage of late-stage breast cancer detected in women, notably by increasing screening coverage rate up to 80% in women aged between 50 and 74 years.’ This Act called for specific programs to target isolated, disabled or deprived women who might be reluctant to participate. This has been partly achieved by the production of videos or tapes for people suffering from visual or hearing deficiencies and the translation of brochures for immigrants. Several campaigns at national and local levels are going to be launched. Patients and women’s associations are involved in this information effort. Cervical cancer screening is offered to women aged 25-69 years every three years. A recent study estimated that 35% of women in the target age group have never or only rarely been screened. Targeted messages will be used to reach these women and coverage could be increased by the participation of GPs (96% of Pap tests are currently carried out by gynaecologists). The 48th objective of the Public Health Act of August 2004 is ‘to continue the annual 2.5% decrease of cervical cancer incidence, notably by increasing screening coverage rate to 80% for women aged 25-69 and HPV test utilization’. Phase 1 of BreastCheck - Ireland's national breast screening program - started in February 2000 and already offers screening in several areas, with coverage expected to be nationwide towards the end of 2007. Breast screening outside the BreastCheck program is available to all women if they are referred by a GP. In Ireland, Phase 1 of a National Cervical Screening Program, which offers free cervical screening to women aged 25-60 years in the Mid-Western Health Board (MWHB) area has recently started. In Italy, screening policies for breast cancer have been inserted in the package of essential levels of care provided by the NHS (Essential Level of Assistance) by Decree “DPCM 29/11/2001.” All National Health Plans have set targets for these areas of prevention. Registers are managed at regional level, however, and screening programs are more widespread in Northern and Central Italy. There is usually a system for targeting and recalling patients, but the target population varies according to regional health plans so the position is varied. In Italy, screening programs for cervical cancer are similar to those for breast cancer. Registers are managed at regional level and screening policies are more widespread in Northern and Central Italy. There is a national program for breast cancer and cervical cancer screening in the Netherlands. National screening programs for cervical cancer are available also in Germany (for the SHI insured). Since 1990 Breast Cancer Detection Programs have been implemented in all Spanish Autonomous Communities. The programs’ target population varies across regions but in most it includes women aged 50-65 years. Cervical cancer screening through cytology is offered to all women aged 35 years and over but there are regional differences. In Catalonia, for example, there is a personalised register of all target individuals (women aged 20-64 years). Cervical cancer screening (Papanicolau technique) is recommended every three to five years. In the Balearic Islands, screening for cervical cancer prevention is opportunistic rather than population-based. Swedish National Guidelines from the National Board of Health and Welfare recommend mammography screening for early detection of breast cancer for age groups 40-74 years. Examination intervals are 18 months for women under 55 years, and 24 months for women over 55. Organised cervical cancer screening has been implemented in Sweden since the mid-1960s. Guidelines for recommended screening are: every third year, for women aged 23-50 years and every fifth year for women aged 51-60. Among the New Member States, a pilot program for breast cancer screening has started in Cyprus and covers women aged 50-69 years. There is a national policy on screening for cervical cancer based on the population register and covering all women aged 25-65 years. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 216 In Estonia, there is a screening program for breast cancer, financed and administered by the Estonian Health Insurance Fund. The target population is women aged 45-59 years, and the screening interval is three years. Mammography screening was introduced in 2002 in Hungary for women aged 45-65 years and screening is repeated bi-annually with a good participation rate. Screening for cancer is included in the prophylactic program for adults in Latvia and covered through the health care budget. For breast cancer, women aged 50 to 69 years are recommended to undergo one mammography every two years. For cervical cancer, women aged 20 to 35 years are recommended to have an oncological test every three years. For women aged 35 to 70 years, the test is carried out annually. In Slovakia, breast cancer screening is provided by the state and paid for by health insurance companies. The target population is women aged 40-60 years and the method is periodical mammography. A national strategy for prophylactic cancer screening (2001-2006) was approved in Bulgaria in 2000. Given the scarce resources available for this strategy, however, it only recommends preventive examinations for cervical cancer as part of regular gynaecological examinations. In Hungary, the gynaecological cervical screening program was launched in 2004. It is based on Papanicolau cytological testing of all women aged 25-65 years every three years. Since July 2004, Lithuania’s Cervical Cancer Prevention Program has been financed by the Compulsory Health Insurance Fund. The program targets women aged 30-60 years and screening is performed every three years. In Slovenia, there is a national policy on screening for cervical cancer that includes all women between the ages of 25 and 64 years. There is active follow-up through a central surveillance system and the screening interval is three years after two initial smears over six months have proved negative. Colorectal cancer A trial for colorectal cancer has started in two of the county councils in Denmark where men and women aged 50-74 years are invited to participate. A pilot project for colorectal cancer screening for 60-69 year old men and women was introduced in 2004 in several Finnish municipalities. Colorectal cancer screening is the 53rd objective of the 2004 Public Health Act and is currently the subject of trials in 22 French départements. People aged 50 to 74 years are invited for a fecal occult blood test (FOBT) every two years. If the result is positive, a colonoscopy is carried out. The program will be assessed shortly to define the national strategy for 2007. Initial results showed an increasing rate of participation (up to 50% in some départements) because of active participation by GPs. 8.4.1 Prevention and screening programs in Austria659 A variety of measures can be related to the promotion of heath:660 • • • • The promotion of a healthy lifestyle The improvement of access to health services and the participation of individuals in decisions regarding their health The promotion of a healthy physical and social environment which facilitates healthy behaviour of individuals The education of individuals about measures to maintain their body in good health 659 Univ.-Prof. Dr. Anita Rieder, Kitty Lawrence BEng. Naidoo J & Wills J. Lehrbuch der Gesundheitsförderung. Herausgegeben von der Bundeszentrale für gesundheitlich Aufklärung BZgA, 2000 660 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 217 Prevention and health promotion are to a large extent publicly financed by the social insurance, the federation (Bund), the individual federal states and the local councils. The central authority for prevention and health promotion in Austria is the Healthy Austria Fund (Fonds Gesundes Österreich, FGÖ).661 Since the Health Promotion Law (Gesundheitsförderungsgesetz) became effective in 1998 it has formed the basis for the work carried out by the Healthy Austria Fund. With an allotted annual budget of around 7.2 million Euros662 the fields of responsibility of the FGÖ include the promotion and support of projects in key areas, encouraging the building of structures for the purposes of health promotion, investment in further and continuing education, promotion of networking between those working in the fields of health promotion and primary information, as well as, provision of information, explanation and the accompanying public activities. In particular projects in the field of health promotion, which aim to promote healthier habits and behavioural patterns, which address praxis-oriented primary prevention, and application-oriented research projects for the further development of health promotion and primary prevention, are supported by the FGÖ. The Supreme Sanitary Council (Oberste Sanitätsrat) was reorganised in May 2005663 and holds a plenary meeting three times a year. It is split into subcommittees, which examine the topics of “vaccination”, “AIDS”, “Mother/Child Passport” and “dental medicine and prophylaxis”. The newly founded Public Health commission is specifically concerned with health at the workplace and “diseases of civilisation”. Several working groups are active in the federal states within the field of prevention with a social medical emphasis including, the Association for Prophylactic Health Activities (Verein für prophylaktische Gesundheitsarbeit, PGA), the Working Group for preventive health care Salzburg (Arbeitskreis für Vorsorgemedizin Salzburg, avos), the Working Group for Preventive Health Care Tyrol (Arbeitskreis für Vorsorgemedizin Tirol, AVOMED), the Working Group for Preventive Health Care and Social Medicine Vorarlberg (Arbeitskreis für Vorsorge- und Sozialmedizin Vorarlberg, aks), the the Health Forum of Lower Austria (Gesundheitsforum Niederösterreich) (Listed in the Austrian Women’s Health Report 2005/2006664) Following a survey carried out between July and November 2004 of around 500 Austrian facilities details of over 100 projects and initiatives, connected with women’s health, were compiled and are described in the document “Women’s Health in Practice” (Frauengesundheit in der Praxis). A few selected examples are listed below demonstrating the variety of topics covered: • • • Exercise to guard against osteoporosis (Osteoporose-Vorbeugeturnen) – run by the Society for the promotion of aging sciences and senior studies, University of Graz (Gesellschaft zur Förderung der Alterswissenschaft und des Seniorenstudiums, Universität Graz). This is an exercise program offered to older women financed by the city of Graz together with course fees. The course aims are to strengthen the health awareness and the resources of older women, improve self confidence and the responsibility for ones own health. Project Gender Mainstreaming in Workplace Health Promotion (Projekt Gender Mainstreaming in der betrieblichen Gesundheitsförderung) run by ppm forschung + beratung in Linz, Upper Austria. The program is financed by the FGÖ, the ÖGB665 and the federal state of Upper Austria. The aim of this project is to pay more attention to the influence of job and work structures on women’s health and to sensitise those working in the field of Health Promotion in the workplace, as well as health and safety in the workplace, to gender issues. Strengthen my back (Meinen Rücken stärken) run by the Women’s Health Centre ISIS in Salzburg and financed by the Salzburg Sickness Fund. This project took the form of an information day which looked at the back in connection with health and, amongst other things, had the aim of 661 Incorporated in the Gesundheit Österreich GmbH (Health Care Austria Plc.) in 2006 Healthy Austria Fund (Fonds Gesundes Österreich) (2004). Yearly report 2004. see also www.fgoe.org 663 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organization on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 664 BMGF Eds. (2006). Austrian Women’s Health Report 2005/2006. Compiled by the Ludwig Boltzmann Institut für Frauenforschung. April 2006. See also www.bmgf.gv.at 665 ÖGB=Österreichischer Gewerkschaftsbund=Austrian Trade Union Federation 662 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 218 • providing information on the consequences of lack of exercise, poor posture, poor diet, and overweight etc. on back problems, and to motivate to undertake preventive exercise programs. (1) Mammografie-Vorsorge; (2) GYN-Vorsorge; (3) Frauen-ALPHA in Vorarlberg. These are continuing area-wide programs run by the aks - Working committee for preventive care and social medicine, non-profit association (Arbeitskreis für Vorsorge- und Sozialmedizin, gemeinnützige Betriebs GmbH). The aims of the gynaecological and mammography programs are the early identification and prevention of illness. In the case of the ALPHA program the aim is to increase wellbeing or quality of life. The programs receive a budget of approx. €180,000 per year for gynaecological examinations (mammography). The ALPHA program is self financed by participants. The Addictive Drug Law (Suchtmittelgesetz, SMG), effective since 1998, forms the central framework for Austrian addictive drug politics. An overview of the organizational structure concerned with drug addiction in Austria is given in Figure 8.10 below.666 Figure 8.10 Overview over the organizational structures related to drugs in Austria Source: ÖBIG (2005). Report on the drug situation. Commissioned by the European monitoring body for drug and drug addiction and the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. See also www.oebig.at At a national level policy, planning and administration are carried out by various federal ministries, such as the Federal Ministry of Health and Women, the Federal Ministry of Justice, the Federal Ministry of Internal Affairs etc. Implementation of preventive measures in the field of drug addiction predominantly takes places at a regional, federal state, level. Each state has an addiction commissioner/coordinator and or a drug commissioner/coordinator. In the Burgenland the role of addiction coordination was transferred to the Psychosozialer Dienst (PSD) or psycho-social services, which are now the main provider of addiction support measures in the Burgenland. In Lower Austria there are also plans to transfer addiction service to an external private insurance carrier. In the year 2001 expenditure in this field was around €8.4 million of which 68% was provided by the individual federal states, around 21% by the federation, and around 6% was provided by towns and councils. 666 ÖBIG (2005). Report on the drug situation. Commissioned by the European monitoring body for drug and drug addiction and the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. See also www.oebig.at LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 219 Great importance is placed on distinguishing between primary and secondary prevention. Primary prevention aims to prevent the onset of an addiction in persons who are not in any particular risk group and in whom an addiction or drug problem has not so far occurred. Secondary prevention is aimed at identified risk groups and at those people who already have initial, but not yet established problems. In the first instance the target group for secondary prevention is young people. Early Detection of diseases and other measures to maintain health of the population are addressed in the General Social Insurance Law (Allgemeines Sozialversicherungsrecht, ASVG) sections regarding health promotion and prevention are cited below: • • • • • § 132a Juvenile health examinations (Jugendlichenuntersuchung) –of 15-18 years olds § 132b Regular precautionary health examinations adult population (Vorsorgeuntersuchung) – for individuals age 18 and older - this has been available since 1973 available and is covered by the Social Health Insurance, a once yearly health check is possible. The new program started in October 2005, “evidence based” prevention program. Within the framework of the annual preventive health checks “Health passports“ are available for age groups mother+child, -40, 40-60, 60+, these come with an additional brochure giving information about a healthy lifestyle and explaining the health examination. A health passport for 75+ will be available in the next months, including an age-specific brochure667, § 7 mother-child passport examinations (Mutter-Kind Pass Untersuchungen) § 132c other measures to maintain health of the population (e.g. active immunization Tick-borne encephalitis, zytogenetic exams) §154b Health promotion Measures to strengthen people’s health • • §155 e.g. convalescent care (Kuraufenthalte) § 156 Measures to prevent diseases - voluntary o E.g. health education, Works-site health promotion, Caring for youth, newborns and pregnant women Other Laws addressing health promotion and prevention: • • • • • • School teaching law 1986 (Schulunterrichtsgesetz, 15.Abschnitt) - Health examination undertaken by the school doctor (Schulärztliche Untersuchung) –- costs are covered by the ministry of education. Occurs once a year668 Health Promotion Law (Gesundheitsförderungsgesetz) since 1998 Health Promotion Fund – financed by value added tax, determined by the financial adjustment law (Finanzausgleichsgesetzes), 7 Million Euro AIDS – Gesetz 1993 - Oberster Sanitätsrat - the supreme health council of Austria has a committee for AIDS Tobacco Law addresses cigarette production, selling, trading, advertising and the protection of nonsmokers Industrial Law (Gewerbeordnung) § 114 Selling alcohol to young people Financial support (Kinderbetreuungsgeld) is made available for those parents absolving 5 examinations during pregnancy and 5 examinations of the child up to the age of 14-18 months. This is covered by the mother-child pass directive (Mutter-Kind Pass Verordnung) 2002. 667 Project Management by Prim.Katharina Pils, co-operation of Univ.-Prof. Dr. Anita Rieder Children’s Health Report (Kindergesundheitsbericht der Stadt Wien 2000) since then no evaluation or analysis of the data, Download available at https://www.wien.gv.at/who/downloads.htm 668 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 220 Examples of projects run by social insurance carriers In the course of the realisation of the socalled innovation projects of social insurance (now defined as standard products of social insurance) a comprehensive project on health promotion and prevention was performed which included topics such as the new programme for health check ups, the health promotion and prevention plan as well as health reporting. Within the area of health promotion behaviour-orientated projects and setting-referred projects were distinguished. The first dealt with topics such as smoking or obesity, the latter with health promotion at the setting workplace and at the setting schools. Reports of these projects are situated at the Hauptverband. Outpatient and inpatient programs to stop smoking are run by the Viennese sickness fund, including also “Bei Anruf Rauchstopp!” whereby counselling and advice are provided over the telephone.669 Since May 2006 the regional sickness fund of Lower Austria provides the „smoking telephone” (Rauchertelefon) in co-operation with other social insurance funds and the federal states.670 “A heart for Vienna” (Ein Herz für Wien) – Aim is, amongst other things, to reduce of risk factors for cardiovascular disease in all target groups by informing and motivating people to make positive changes in lifestyle factors such as stopping smoking taking more exercise, healthier nutrition etc. This project is run by the area management for social- and health planning as well as financial management (Bereichsleitung für Sozial- und Gesundheitsplanung sowie Finanzmanagement, BGF) and by the regional sickness fund of Vienna (WGKK). 671 The project management is undertaken by the Fund Social Vienna (Fonds Soziales Wien, FSW) by order of the city of Vienna. Health promotion and prevention 2006 (Gesundheitsförderung und Prävention 2006) is an area wide program run by the Lower Austria sickness fund. 256 events were held during which tips for a healthier lifestyle were passed on and also looking at designing a health promoting environment (school, work place, local authority). Programs are offered in a variety of areas including exercise, nutrition, cancer and prevention, and mental fitness.672 „ Slim without dieting” (Schlank ohne Diät) – weight loss program offered by the regional sickness fund of Lower Austria (NÖGKK). 673 Projekt Betrieb Aktiv – gestalten und bewegen (the active workplace – design and move) – a joint project between the regional sickness fund of Upper Austria and AUVA, the Austrian Social Insurance for Occupational Risks (Allgemeine Unfallversicherungsanstalt).674 Project “Trainees in motion” (Projekt Lehrlinge in Bewegung) – A health promotion project in the workplace run in the Trainee workshops of the Voest Alpine Stahl Linz GmbH.675 The project aimed to make health-conscious working an integrated part of the training. All trainees who started their training in autumn 1994 were supervised by a sports scientist, work physicians as well as apprenticeship trainers during their entire apprenticeship (traineeship) with relation to formfitting (körpergerecht) work. A sport scientist employed by the regional sickness fund of Upper Austria developed compensation exercises, solutions for formfitting work based on work related back-school as well as ergonomical options for improvement. Together with specialists of the centre for work medicine the trainees elaborated workspecific dangers and burdens.676 669 Wiener Gebietskrankenkasse, accessed at www.wgkk.at Niederösterreichische Gebietskrankenkasse, accessed at www.noegkk.at 671 Wiener Gebietskrankenkasse, accessed at www.wgkk.at 672 Niederösterreichische Gebietskrankenkasse, accessed at www.noegkk.at 673 Allgemeine Unfallversicherungsanstalt, AUVA, accessed at www.auva.at 674 Oberösterreichische Gebietskrankenkasse, accessed at www.ooegkk.at 675 Oberösterreichische Gebietskrankenkasse, accessed at www.ooegkk.at 676 Oberösterreichische Gebietskrankenkasse, accessed at www.ooegkk.at 670 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 221 Project “employees move employees” (MitarbeiterInnen bewegen MitarbeiterInnen) – - a joint project of the Upper Austria sickness fund and the AUVA, the Austrian Social Insurance for Occupational Risks (Allgemeine Unfallversicherungsanstalt).677 Preventive information dissemination campaigns have been carried out in Austria. These have often been carried out in schools. Furthermore financial support has been made available for patients. Screening and Vaccination The Austrian Federal Institute for Health (Österreichisches Bundesinstitut für Gesundheitswesen, ÖBIG678), whose activities focus on health management and environmental protection, has produced a series of documents on the topic of screening and preventive care. Publications include: • • • • • Mammographie - Screening Austria 2005 (Mammography screening in Austria) – guidelines for implementation in Austria. These projects were based on the EU-criteria for breast cancer screening and coordinated by the ÖBIG (Austrian Health Agency) Screening aus ökonomischer Perspektive - Dickdarmkarzinom (2004) (Screening from an economic perspective – colon carcinoma 2004) – literature-based analysis on whether CT coloscopy is a cost effective screening method in the early detection of colon cancer. Impfungen – ökonomische Evaluation 2003 (Vaccination – economic evaluation). A study of the Austria vaccination system, an evaluation of the economic benefit of vaccinations (meta-analysis) and a cost-benefit analysis using the example of measles. Impfplan 2006 (Vaccination plan 2006) – published by the Ministry of Health and Women. Lists which vaccinations are recommended and at what age they should be carried out. Also details which illnesses may be prevented through immunisation. Recently much attention has been paid to drawing up a ”Pandemieplan” a pandemic plan in light of the avarian influenza or bird flu threat. Other Screening Programs in the Health Reform Law 2005 include: • • National Programs on molecular genetic analysis for breast cancer and ovarian cancer. Screening the newborns – since the mid60s, screening has been carried out for hereditary metabolic diseases679 Screening costs are covered by the Federation, treatments are covered by the social health insurance. Evaluation The evaluation and quality aim of the mammography screening programs is the continual evaluation of structure, process and results. The data are made directly available to all those concerned in order to achieve uniform diagnosis and treatment standards. The report “Life expectancy and Mortality in Vienna” (2003) the increase or rather high rate of breast cancer is attributed to the “screening-effect”. Mammography screening has been made available free of charge since 1974. A study has shown that although the number of tumours from stage II has increased in most age groups since 1982, at the same time a decreasing trend, also in the higher tumour stages, has been observed in all age groups over the past few years. The authors state that the decrease in advanced stage tumours and mortality can plausibly be related to the screening prevalence.680 677 Allgemeine Unfallversicherungsanstalt, AUVA, accessed at www.auva.at Recently integrated into the Health Care Austria Plc. (Gesundheit Österreich GmbH), see www.oebig.at 679 www.kinderklinik.meduniwien.ac.at 680 Vutuc C et al. Wiener Klin Wochenschr 1998;110/13-14:485-490 678 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 222 Examples of published results of the evaluation of Austrian prevention programs & services681 Vorarlberg Health Monitoring and Promotion Program Based on the approximately 700,000 health examinations carried out on around 170,000 people in Vorarlberg between 1985 – 2004, together with the CINDI population surveys, the stability of several cardiovascular risk factors was tracked over time, the predictive value of raised or lowered total cholesterol in men and women compared, actual trends for risk factors determined etc. A number of publications have been published. The long term tracking of cardiovascular risk factors682 showed that whilst fewer than 20% of the participants were able to lower their BMI between examinations, around 50% did reduce their heightened blood pressure. The expediency of the health examination recall system was demonstrated.683 Participants who were invited and attended a repeat examination within 1.5 years of the first, had higher values for various risk factors, but also a comparatively more favourable outcome. The predictive accuracy of SCORE risk function for cardiovascular disease in clinical practice was evaluated with 44,649 men and women.684 The mental well-being in women in preventive medicine program was studied and found that the in terms of depression in women this topic was given too little attention in a general preventive medical setting.685 Other aspects studied include Gamma-Glutamyl Transferrase as a risk factor for cardiovascular mortality, seasonal variations in risk factor profiles and mortality, gender differences in risk factors related to cardiovascular mortality and all-cause mortality. See Appendix 17 for a list of related publications. 20 year evaluation of national blood pressure education campaigns Public awareness was evaluated following a nationwide educational campaign on hypertension.686 This study found that although initially awareness was increased the effect dropped off again. Mother-child-Passport A marked decrease of infant mortality took place since the middle of the 1970s. Whereas in the 1970ies almost 300 infants per 1000 newly ‘live’ borns died, since the 90ies this number lies below 10.687 This success is especially attributed to the introduction of the mother-child-passport and decreased fertility of women older than 35 years.688 Furthermore the development of birth weight 1970-1995, which has increased by 60g in the mean birth weight, could partly be due to the extensive use of maternity care program (mother-child-passport). However the reduced maternity payment in 1997 may lead to reduction in the use of the program.689 681 Univ.-Prof. Dr. Anita Rieder, Kitty Lawrence BEng. Ulmer, H., Kelleher, C., Diem, G., Concin, H. (2003). ”Long-term tracking of cardiovascular risk factors among men and women in a large population-based health system. The Vorarlberg Health Monitoring & Promotion Program.” European Heart Journal 24 (11), pp. 1004-1013 683 Ulmer, H., Kollerits, B., Kelleher, C., Diem, G., Concin, H. (2005). Predictive accuracy of the SCORE risk function for cardiovascular disease in clinical practice: a prospective evaluation of 44 649 Austrian men and women.” European Journal of Cardiovascular Prevention and Rehabilitation 12(5), pp.433-441 684 ibid 685 Concin, H. Ulmer, H. Hefler, L. (2002). ”Mental well-being in 5000 women participating in the Women-Plus preventive medicine program.” Maturitas 41 Suppl 1, pp.9-12. 686 Schmeisser-Rieder, A., Kunze, U. (2000). ”Blood pressure awareness in Austria. A 20-year evaluation, 19781998.” European Heart Journal, 21, pp.414-420 687 Life expectancy and Mortality in Vienna (2003). Published by Magistrat der Stadt Wien Bereichsleitung für Gesundheitsplanung und Finanzmanagement. Vienna 688 Waldhör, T., Vutuc, C. (1995). ”Trendanalyse der Säuglingssterblichkeit unter besonderer Berücksichtigung der perinatalen Mortalität in Österreich(1965-1991).” Das Gesundheitswesen 57(1), pp.13-16 689 Waldhör, T., Haidinger, G., Vutuc, C. (1997). ”Development of birth weight in Austria from 1970-1995.” Wiener Klinische Wochenschrift 109(20), pp.804-807 682 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 223 Evaluation of Austrian Newborn Hearing Screening The Universal Neonatal Hearing Screening (UNHS) has been gradually implemented since the nineties in Austrian maternity wards and neonatal intensive care units. An evaluation was carried out by means of a retrospective analysis of clinical data of 394 Austrian children. It was found that UNHS greatly increases the proportion of children whose hearing impairment is diagnosed before six months of age.690 Hearing screening of pre-school children at nursery schools in Tyrol, Austria was evaluated and it was determined that hearing screening is an efficient means of assessing ear and hearing problems in pre-school children, follow up-rate needs to be improved in order to optimise efficacy.691 Evaluation of the prenatal diagnosis of limb reduction deficiencies – EUROSCAN Group Data from Congenital Malformation Registries (12 European Countries, including Austria), study Period 1996-98, ultrasound scans in the mid-trimester of pregnancy.692 PSA screening for Prostate cancer The possible effect of prostate-specific antigen (PSA) testing on prostate cancer mortality has remained controversial, despite the test's widespread application. In Tyrol a study was carried out to monitor the impact of prostate screening. PSA test was made freely available from 1993. The study found that a policy of making PSA testing freely available is associated with a reduction in prostate cancer mortality. Trends in reduction differ significantly between Tyrol and the rest of Austria693. A significant migration to lower clinical and pathological stages has been observed since the introduction of this screening program.694 PSA testing became widely available in Austria not before 1989. Age-specific mortality trends for prostate cancer before and after the introduction of (opportunistic) screening were analysed between1970-2002. After 12 years of follow-up, significant reductions in mortality rates could not be observed in the age groups 50-59, 60-69, and 80-89; significant decreases were found in the age group 70-79, which cannot be related to PSA screening. PSA screening does not appear to reduce prostate cancer mortality in a uniform cohort of men with equal access to health care, however, given the long lead-time for prostate cancer, even longer follow up may still be needed to detect any important trends695. The calculations were done for Austria without Tyrol and for Tyrol. Evaluation of “Heart for Vienna”696 Ein Herz für Wien (a Heart for Vienna project) was evaluated and the report sent to the Department for Health Planning and Financial Management (Bereichsleitung für Gesundheitsplanung und Finanzmanagement). The program was also reported in Weißbuch Prävention! HERZgesund? KKH Kaufmännische Krankenkasse (Hrsg.).697 The annual report of the KKH (Commercial Sickness Fund 690 Weichbold, V., Nekahm-Heis, D., Welzl-Müller, K. (2005). ” Zehn Jahre Neugeborenen-Hörscreening in Österreich: Eine Evaluierung.” Wiener Klinische Wochenschrift 117(18), pp.641-6 691 Weichbold, V., Rohrer M, Winkler, C., Welzl-Muller, K. (2004). ”Hearing screening at nursery schools: results of an evaluation study.” Wiener Klinische Wochenschrift 116(14), pp.478-83 692 Stoll, C., Diesel, A., Quiesser-Luft, A., Froster, U., Bianca, S., Clementi, M. (2000). ”Evaluation of the prenatal diagnosis of limb reduction deficiencies. EUROSCAN Study Group.” Prenat Diagn.20(10), pp. 811-8. 693 Bartsch, G., Horninger, W., Klocker, H. et a (2001).“Prostate cancer mortality after introduction of prostate-specific antigen mass screening in the Federal State of Tyrol, Austria.“ Urology 58, pp.417-424 694 Horninger, W., Berger, A., Pelzer, A., Klocker, H., Oberaigner, W., Schonitzer, D., Severi, G., Robertson, C., Boyle, P., Bartsch, G. (2004). ”Screening for prostate cancer: updated experience from the Tyrol study.” Curr Urol Rep. 5(3), pp.220-5. 695 Vutuc, C., Schernhammer, E.S., Haidinger, G., Waldhör, T. (2005). ” Prostate cancer and prostate-specific antigen (PSA) screening in Austria.” Wiener Klinische Wochenschrift 117(13-14), pp.457-61 696 Rieder, A. (2006). A Heart for Vienna – a Viennese prevention program. Presentation See also: Aigner G. (2006). Legal aspects of prevention and health promotion. Document for the university course „Master of Public Health: prevention and health promotion (MPH)“ 2005/2006 Vienna. 697 Walter U et al. (2004). Abschnitt 10.4 “Ein Herz für Wien“ – eine Stadt widmet sich der Herzgesundheit ihrer Bewohner. In Weißbuch Prävention “Herzgesund?” Jahresreport der Kaufmännische Krankenkasse Hannover 2004 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 224 Hannover) 2004. The external evaluation included and expert inquiry, telephone survey (6,000 interviews) preparation of an external report evaluating the results, professional external report on the program. The evaluation showed a positive reaction to the program among both the experts and the general public. The aims were classified as important and correct. The strengths of the program lie therein, that the social environmental factors are taken into account and are built around evidence-based interventions. The program was found to be well incorporated in the medical and health promotional professional environment. 8.5 Health inequalities International studies in socioeconomic determinants of health are helpful to determine the patterns of socioeconomic health inequalities in Europe. Large education-related inequalities in self-assessed health were observed in Austria, Denmark, England, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, West Germany, Spain, and Sweden (Table 8.5) with large differences in magnitude.698 Between the 1980s and the 1990s, socioeconomic inequalities in self-assessed health remained, on average, stable for men but slightly increased for women. Increasing inequalities were observed in Italy, the Netherlands and Spain, but this was not seen in Northern countries. This suggests that Northern countries’ welfare states had mechanisms to protect people in lower socioeconomic classes from the health effects of the economic crises in the 1990s. However, large socioeconomic inequalities in reported health status still persist in all the 10 western countries analysed. Table 8.5 Magnitude of educational differences in fair/poor self-assessed health: men and women aged 25-69 years (Odds ratiosa, 95% confidence intervals) Men Women Country 1980s 1990s 1980s 1990s Finland 3.15 (2.55-3.88) 2.99 (2.44-3.66) 2.86 (2.28-3.58) 3.29 (2.60-4.18) Norway 2.37 (1.71-3.29) 2.37 (1.70-3.30) 3.32 (2.37-4.66) 3.06 (2.22-4.23) Denmark 2.93 (2.16-3.9) 2.30 (1.73-3.04) 3.10 (2.13-4.50) 2.84 (2.10-3.82) England 3.11 (2.27-4.25) 3.08 (2.57-3.68) 2.08 (1.59-2.71) 2.66 (2.21-3.19) Netherlands 2.95 (2.46-3.52) 2.81 (2.39-3.30) 1.95 (1.63-2.35) 2.12 (1.81-2.49) W. Germany 1.50 (1.20-1.88) 1.76 (1.44-2.14) 1.89 (1.43-2.50) 1.91 (1.50-2.44) Austria 3.39 (2.92-3.93) 3.22(2.79-3.71) 2.75 (2.37-3.19) 2.67 (2.31-3.07) Italy 2.05(1.79-2.34) 2.94 (2.54-3.40) 1.86 (1.62-2.15) 2.55 (2.20-2.95) Spain 1.86 (1.56-2.17) 2.58 (1.81-3.67) 1.97 (1.63-2.37) 3.10 (2.18-4.41) Tot (excl. Italy) 2.61 (2.41-2.83) 2.54 (2.35-2.75) 2.48 (2.28-2.69) 2.70 (2.50-2.92) a The reference category in all countries in higher educational level Source: Kunst et al. 2005. Education-related inequalities in common chronic diseases were found in Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Great Britain, Italy, the Netherlands, and Spain.699 Most diseases showed higher prevalence among people with low educational level, only allergy was more common in the high education group (Table 24). High inequalities favouring the better-off are observed for stroke, diseases of the nervous system, diabetes and arthritis. No statistically significant inequality was found for cancer, kidney and skin diseases. The size of socioeconomic differences in chronic diseases varied between men and women. For diabetes, hypertension, and heart diseases inequalities were higher among women; while for back and spinal cord disorders inequality was higher among men. By comparing the working-age and the elderly population groups, it is evident that on average education-related inequalities decreased when age increased, the only exceptions were chronic respiratory diseases, headache and migraine. Among the working-age group cancer 698 A.E. Kunst et al., "Trends in Socioeconomic Inequalities in Self-Assessed Health in 10 European Countries," International Journal of Epidemiology 34, no. 2 (2005). 699 J.A.A. Dalstra et al., "Socioeconomic Differences in the Prevalence of Common Chronic Diseases: An Overview of Eight European Countries," International Journal of Epidemiology 34, no. 2 (2005). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 225 was more prevalent in the low educated group but in old age the pattern reversed; among older people cancer appears to affect the better educated. Socioeconomic differences in self-assessed health status are found also in eastern European countries such as Russia, Estonia, Lithuania, Latvia, Hungary, Poland and Czech Republic; and the findings are not dissimilar from those in the EU-15.700 Education and material deprivation are important determinants of health status; people with higher education are less likely to report poor health (OR: 0.36). Low perceived control in work was also significantly associated with poor health, even after adjusting not only for age and gender but also for education, deprivation, and inequality. Table 8.6 Education differences (low compared to high education) for chronic disease groups in Europe (OR with 95% confidence intervals) Total Men Women Men and women (25-59 years) Men and women (60-79 years) Stroke 1.64 (1.401.93) 1.70 (1.352.14) 1.56 (1.251.96) 1.89 (1.252.51) 1.53 (1.27-1.86) Diseases nervous system 1.63 (1.511.77) 1.57 (1.401.77) 1.57 (1.411.75) 1.81 (1.641.99) 1.33 (1.17-1.52) Diabetes mellitus 1.60 (1.431.80) 1.30 (1.111.51) 2.19 (1.822.63) 1.64 (1.381.94) 1.57 (1.34-1.84) Arthritis 1.56 (1.401.73) 1.50 (1.271.77) 1.46 (1.261.68) 2.04 (1.762.36) 1.17 (1.01-1.36) Hypertension 1.42 (1.341.50) 1.10 (1.001.22) 1.52 (1.421.62) 1.55 (1.431.67) 1.30 (1.20-1.40) Stomach/duodenum ulcer 1.40(1.221.60) 1.41(1.191.67) 1.56(1.251.95) 1.37(1.151.62) 1.461.16-1.83) Genitourinary diseases 1.35(1.241.47) 1.29(1.131.48) 1.53(1.361.72) 1.51(1.361.69) 1.15(1.00-1.31) Headache/migraine 1.35(1.271.43) 1.18(1.061.32) 1.29(1.20-1.3) 1.28(1.201.37) 1.62(1.42-1.84) Osteoarthrosis 1.34(1.211.49) 1.32(1.121.55) 1.29(1.121.48) 1.51(1.301.75) 1.20(1.03-1.38) Liver/gall diseases 1.26(1.081.46) 1.10(0.871.40) 1.30(1.071.58) 1.31(1.071.60) 1.19(0.95-1.49) Chronic respiratory diseases 1.24(1.151.33) 1.33(1.201.48) 1.19(1.071.33) 1.13(1.031.25) 1.42(1.26-1.61) Heart diseases 1.22(1.101.35) 1.18(1.041.34) 1.51(1.281.79) 1.29(1.091.53) 1.18(1.04-1.33) Back and spinal cord disorders 1.19(1.111.29) 1.33(1.191.49) 1.05(0.941.16) 1.29(1.181.41) 0.98(0.86-1.13) Cancer 1.13(.0981.30) 0.96(0.781.20) 1.22(1.021.46) 1.64(1.021.46) 0.77(0.64-0.93) Kidney stones and other kidney diseases 1.11(0.951.31) 1.03(0.831.27) 1.34(1.041.72) 1.17(0.951.45) 1.03(0.80-1.33) Chronic disease group 700 M. Bobak et al., "Socioeconomic Factors, Material Inequalities, and Perceived Control in Self-Rated Health: CrossSectional Data from Seven Post-Communist Countries," Social Science and Medicine 51 (2000). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 226 Skin diseases 0.99(0.911.08) 0.99(0.861.14) 0.98(0.871.11) 0.98(0.881.09) 10.3(0.86-1.23) Allergy 0.73(0.660.81) 0.67(0.570.79) 0.72(0.630.82) 0.69(0.610.78) 0.82(0.68-0.99) Source: Dalstra et al. 2005 There has been some attempt to compare health inequalities across countries. One such study found that education- and occupation- related inequalities in mortality favouring the better-off have increased between 1981-1985 and 1991-1995 in Denmark, England and Wales, Norway, Sweden, Italy (Turin), and particularly so, among Finnish men.701 The main cause of this widening gap was the proportional faster relative decline of mortality in the higher socioeconomic classes although the decrease in absolute mortality has been similar in the lower and upper groups. A similar decline in cardiovascular mortality was recorded for all six countries and in all socioeconomic classes, but again the relative decline was larger among the rich.702 Socioeconomic differences in cardiovascular mortality explained almost half of the widening relative gap in mortality in all populations but Italy. Changes in other causes of deaths also contributed to the widening gap. The authors considered also the socioeconomic change in three other causes of mortality: neoplasms, other diseases and injuries. The occupation gap for neoplasms between the 1980s and 1990s increased in Sweden, England/Wales and Italy; for other diseases an increase was seen in Finland and Sweden; and for injuries in Finland and Italy. The widening in inequality in total mortality was also caused by increasing rates of mortality in the lower socioeconomic classes for lung cancer, breast cancer, respiratory diseases and gastrointestinal diseases among both men and women in almost all countries but Italy. Men and women with lower education level had significantly higher stroke mortality than those with a middle/high educational level in Finland, Norway, Denmark, England/Wales, Belgium, Switzerland, Austria, Italy (Turin), and Spain (Barcelona and Madrid).703 The magnitude of education inequalities in stroke mortality was similar across Europe; only Austria reported larger than average differences for both men and women. The risk of dying from stroke was approximately 26% and 28% higher for men and women with low educational level than those in high education. On average, educational differences tended to decrease with age; faster declines were seen in Norway, Austria, and Barcelona. The reduction with age was not statistically significant in England/Wales, Turin and Madrid. The contribution of education inequalities in stroke mortality to the overall education differences in life expectancy at age 30 years was 7% among men and 14% among women. The elimination of education inequalities in stroke mortality would have reduced education differences in life expectancy by 9% among men and 18% among women in Turin, and by 7% and 18% respectively in Austria. As emphasized above, income and income inequality affect material circumstances both directly and indirectly through social participation and degree of control. Indeed, OECD countries with greater trade union membership and female political representation have lower child mortality.704 Quality of the psychosocial environment is only moderately and inconsistently associated with mortality; but greater distrust and lack of control are related with higher coronary heart disease mortality. Low control in the workplace was related to higher risk of cardiovascular disease in the Whitehall II study705. Less control is 701 J.P. Mackenbach et al., "Widening Socioeconomic Inequalities in Mortality in Six Western European Countries," International Journal of Epidemiology 32 (2003). 702 Ibid. 703 M. Avendano et al., "Educational Level and Stroke Mortality: A Comparison of 10 European Populations During the 1990s," Stroke 35 (2004). 704 J. Lynch et al., "Income Inequality, the Psychosocial Environment, and Health: Comparisons of Wealthy Nations," Lancet 358 (2001). 705 H. Bosma et al., "Low Job Control and Risk of Coronary Heart Disease in Whitehall Ii (Prospective Cohort) Study," British Medical Journal 314 (1997). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 227 also associated with higher death rates also in Latvia, Lithuania, Estonia, Hungary, Poland and Czech Republic.706 Public health policies to tackle inequalities in health Health inequalities are increasingly recognised as an important public health issue throughout Europe. Reducing inequalities in health requires a multi-sectoral approach that addresses not only health and social care service provision and poverty alleviation, but also housing, environment, diets, smoking and alcohol consumption. The extent to which countries are embracing this inter-sectoral approach to policy-making is described in more detail below. Almost all EU Member States have identified the reduction of health inequalities as a goal of the public health or broader health policy; however in some countries this goal is outlined more explicitly than in others. Significant policy developments have been seen in England, the Netherlands and Sweden in reducing health inequalities, although to date there has been little evidence that they have been successful. In contrast to the more central-led policies in England, the Netherlands has embarked on program of local experiments with a strong emphasis on evaluation. However national implementation has been hindered due to a period of political instability between2002-2003. According to a recent report funded by the UK Presidency reviewing national-level policies and strategies to reduce social inequalities in health, there is no EU Member State that is making a concerted effort to reduce the social gradient in health.707 Despite widespread attention paid to socioeconomic inequalities in health across countries, there remains considerable variation in the form and nature of the policy goals and targets. These differences can be attributed to: availability of data about the nature and extent of inequalities; differing levels of political will; state of economic development; and the role of international agencies. The report goes on to categorise countries according to the scope of their national strategies to reduce health inequalities: 1. The UK and Ireland have well-developed and coordinated action plans 2. The Netherlands, Finland, Denmark, Hungary, Italy, Poland and Sweden incorporates health equity into broader public health policies 3. Belgium (Flanders) and France have developed a series of programs to reduce health inequalities, but they are not necessarily part of a broader policy 4. Cyprus and Greece lack a distinctive focus on health inequalities, but have developed some programs directed towards social determinants of health at national and local levels The remaining countries have no explicit national health inequalities policy, but many acknowledge the problem, as reflected in various policy statements. Since the mid-1980s, reducing inequalities has been a major policy objective in Sweden.708 The formation of the National Institute for Public Health in 1991 further strengthened the support for equality in health. More recently, Sweden has undergone structured policy developments in the area of health inequalities709. To address the relationship between labour market and working conditions and health inequalities, Swedish labour market policies offer strong employment protection and actively promote participation in the labour market for people with chronic illness. These policies have been found to protect these vulnerable groups from labour-market exclusion. In addition, Sweden has made considerable progress in health impact assessments, specifically in assessing the effect on health inequalities of the European Community agricultural policy. Furthermore, general social policy measures are in place to improve the health and well706 M. Marmot and M. Bobak, "International Comparators and Poverty and Health in Europe," British Medical Journal 321 (2000). 707 K. Judge et al., "Health Inequalities: A Challenge for Europe.," in Report prepared for the UK Presidency of the EU. (2005). 708 B. Burström et al., "Sweden," in Reducing Inequalities in Health: A European Perspective, ed. J Mackenbach and M Bakker (London: Routledge, 2002). 709 J.P. Mackenbach and M.J. Bakker, "Tackling Socio-Economic Inequalities in Health: Analysis of European Experiences," Lancet 362 (2003). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 228 being of lone mothers, such as subsidized public childcare. The recent national public health program has the goal of creating the “societal conditions that ensure good health on equal terms for the entire population”. This program emphasizes social connections such as social capital, supportive social environment, and a secure bond between children and their parents. In addition, there are strong ethical undertones, such as a sense of solidarity. Although for many years Sweden has been pursuing equalityoriented health and social policies, there are nowadays some indications that inequalities are increasing. Therefore, continued efforts to research and develop wide-reaching policies are needed. In England there has been considerable effort directed to researching and developing policies to reduce health inequalities – being some of the largest in Europe. Indeed some argue that the program in the United Kingdom is one of the most coherent and ambitious to date.710 In July 2003, a national health inequalities strategy was launched: Tackling Health Inequalities: A Program for Action. This strategy aimed to review progress against the 2010 health inequalities Public Service Agreement (PSA) target from 2002 and 12 national headline indicators. The target was: By 2010 to reduce inequalities in health outcomes whole by 10% as measured by infant mortality and life expectancy at birth.- both between routine and manual groups and the population as a whole, and local authorities with the fifth of areas with lowest life expectancy at birth and the population as a whole. The overall aim was to prevent health inequalities from worsening, given that the long-term trend showed that the gap in mortality between professional (social class I) and unskilled manual men (social class V) has increased by two and a half times since 1930–32. By 2004, there was no narrowing of health inequalities against the PSA target. On the contrary, there was a widening of inequalities in infant mortality and life expectancy (between 1997 and 2005), reflecting the long-term trend. However, on a more positive note, some progress has been made in reducing child poverty (the proportion of children in absolute poverty has been halved in five years) and improving housing (specifically, the proportion of households living in nondecent housing”). According to the most recent national public health policy in 2004 (Choosing Health), all government departments now systematically take into account the impacts of new policy proposals on health and health inequalities. In Cyprus, two simultaneous policies to reduce health inequalities were developed in 2003: 1) the National Action Plan for Social Inclusion included among its targets the reduction of disparities; and 2) the Health Council identified the need to increase health services in rural areas and implementing preventive programs in community and schools in an attempt to reduce inequalities. Greece passed legislation in June 2005 regarding the organization and operation of public health services, with emphasis placed on reducing socioeconomic inequalities. One of the difficulties encountered in developing and monitoring a strategy to reduce inequalities is limited data on inequalities, as seen in Italy. In the Czech Republic, inequalities in health are not identified as a priority issue in health policy and little data are available. Similarly in Malta, health inequalities are not featured prominently on the political agenda, partly due to lack of epidemiological data and research in this area, and party due to the misconception that by offering health service free at the point of use to poor members of society inequalities would stop being a problem. Although there is increasing evidence on the presence of health inequalities in Estonia, they have received little attention to date. Latvia and Lithuania address health inequalities explicitly in their public health policies. In addition, Latvia is beginning to develop the first national action plan on poverty and social exclusion for 2004-2006 (as in Malta). In Hungary there is some focus on regional inequalities in health – and current health policies are addressing this issue alongside data collection in order to continue to measure its progress. While the primary focus of policies addressing inequalities in health is the socioeconomic dimension, some countries, like Hungary, also address ethnic differences (specifically, the Roma population). 710 A. Couffinhal et al., "Policies for Reducing Inequalities in Health, What Role Can the Healthcare System Play? A European Perspective. Part Ii. Experience from Europe.," in News bulletin in economy of health, no. 93. (Paris: IRDES, 2005). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 229 8.6 Health trends in Austria This section gives a general overview of the trends in certain population health indicators over the past 10 years.711 Between 1995 and 2004, life expectancy at birth increased from 77.12 to 79.47 years. Male life expectancy increased from 73.67 to 76.52 years, and women’s life expectancy increased slightly less, from 80.27 to 82.18 years, thus narrowing the gender gap. Life expectancy at birth lies slightly above the EUaverage and has developed better than the EU-average over the past ten years. Within Austria there is a visible east-west divide in male life expectancy. While men in the western provinces of Tirol, Vorarlberg and Salzburg live particularly long, the life expectancy of Viennese men is approximately one year below the Austrian average. Compared to the Austrian average, life expectancy of Viennese women is even more unfavourable than it is for men.712 Figure 8.11 Life expectancy at birth in Austria 84 82 80 78 76 74 72 70 68 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Austria total EU total Austria women EU women 2001 2002 Austria men 2003 2004 EU men Source: Health for All Database, updated January 2006, accessed: 7.03.06 Life expectancy at older ages provides an indication of advances in health care and also public health programs. In 1995, life expectancy at the age of 65 was approximately 17.45, similar to the EU average, but has slightly diverged from it since then, to 18.87 in 2004 (EU-average: 18.29). This recent improvement is due largely to declining mortality for older men. Healthy life expectancy (HALE), referring to the estimated period of a lifetime spent in full health was 71.4 years in 2002. Men can expect to live 69.3 years in full health, while women can expect 73.5 years. However, that also entails that while women live longer on average, they also spend a longer period of their lives not living in full health. Healthy life expectancy remained more or less stable from 1999 to 2002. That may indicate that the increase in overall life expectancy can rather be attributed to improvements in treatment of diseases than to the prevention of disease. 711 712 The majority of this section was written by Mag. Daniel Hentschel, MSc. BMGF (2004). Healthcare report Austria.Vienna LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 230 Figure 8.12 Life expectancy at the age of 65 in Austria 25 20 15 10 5 0 1995 1996 Austria total 1997 EU total 1998 1999 2000 Austria men 2001 2002 EU men 2003 Austria women 2004 EU women Source: Health for All Database, updated January 2006, accessed 07/03/2006 Table 8.7 Infant mortality (per 1000 live births) 1995 1996 1997 1998 5.42 5.08 4.74 4.92 Austria 6.01 5.28 5.57 Belgium Cyprus 7.7 6.05 5.86 5.21 Czech Republic 5.06 5.51 5.15 4.43 Denmark 14.88 10.5 10.1 9.37 Estonia 3.98 3.92 3.93 4.13 Finland 4.86 4.77 4.73 4.58 France 5.3 4.98 4.86 4.67 Germany 8.15 7.25 6.44 6.68 Greece 10.66 10.91 9.86 9.7 Hungary 6.37 5.98 6.08 5.86 Ireland 6.19 6.15 5.65 5.26 Italy 18.85 15.92 15.35 14.99 Latvia 12.48 10.08 10.34 9.27 Lithuania 4.06 4.39 3.45 4.83 Luxembourg 8.89 10.72 6.41 5.35 Malta 5.46 5.74 5.04 5.19 Netherlands 13.6 12.21 10.18 9.53 Poland 7.51 6.87 6.43 6.02 Portugal 10.99 10.19 8.7 8.79 Slovakia 5.53 4.74 5.17 5.21 Slovenia 5.49 5.54 5.03 4.86 Spain 4.03 3.83 3.63 3.56 Sweden 6.18 6.09 5.86 5.69 United Kingdom LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 1999 4.36 2000 4.83 2001 4.84 2002 4.06 2003 4.46 2004 4.47 6 4.62 4.17 9.58 3.7 4.32 4.54 6.15 8.43 5.88 5.21 11.29 8.65 4.12 7.2 5.23 8.85 5.63 8.31 4.51 4.47 3.4 5.78 5.56 4.1 4.96 8.42 3.61 4.38 4.38 5.91 9.22 6.17 4.51 10.37 8.61 2.97 5.96 5.13 8.11 5.54 8.58 4.9 4.38 3.42 5.58 4.9 3.97 4.63 8.79 3.22 4.45 4.31 5.1 8.13 6.04 4.67 11.04 7.92 4.95 4.32 5.37 7.67 5.06 6.24 4.23 4.08 3.66 5.48 5 4.15 4.08 3.9 3.75 5.69 2.97 4.1 4.22 5.12 7.16 6.98 3.21 3.34 4.23 4.02 7.29 4.14 9.85 7.93 3.93 5.89 5.02 7.52 5.07 7.63 3.83 4.15 3.28 5.23 9.44 6.73 4.9 5.7 4.8 7.04 4.19 9.38 7.89 3.48 5.92 4.39 3.98 3.92 231 EU 6.72 6.36 5.9 5.66 5.4 5.21 5.06 4.89 4.77 4.75 Source: Health for All Database (World Health Report), Update January 2006, accessed 07/03/2006 Infant mortality in Austria has decreased significantly in the course of the past decades (from approximately 27 deaths in 1970 to approx. 4.5 in 2004 per 1000 live births ), which can mainly be attributed to a decline in perinatal deaths (see following table).713 This is due to technological improvements, improved access to pre- and postnatal care for pregnant women as well as better nutrition. As a result, Austria is one of the European countries with the lowest infant mortality. Throughout the past years, infant mortality has remained relatively stable, possibly indicating that a further decrease cannot be attained solely by medical measures, but only through a reduction of the prevalence of risk factors such as alcohol, overweight and smoking. Table 8.8 Perinatal mortality rate per 1000 births 1995 1996 1997 1998 4.4 4.2 3.98 4.07 Austria 6.96 7.21 7.38 Belgium Cyprus 4.96 4.82 4.28 4.5 Czech Republic 5.91 6.09 6.51 5.87 Denmark 10.46 9.62 9.75 7.59 Estonia 4.2 3.84 3.84 3.96 Finland 7.42 7.22 7.04 6.99 France 4.57 4.41 4.31 3.96 Germany 10.33 9.51 9.42 8.78 Greece 6.73 6,3 6.95 6.12 Hungary 10.59 9.98 9.6 9.47 Ireland 5.47 5.43 5.01 6.44 Italy 17.12 15.92 14.79 11.85 Latvia 10 7.21 7.69 8.01 Lithuania 5.7 4.38 6.87 8.49 Luxembourg 9.94 13.47 9.26 8.2 Malta 8.09 8.41 7.93 7.84 Netherlands 10.5 9.62 8.33 7.93 Poland 7.21 6.77 5.93 5.8 Portugal 7.76 8.5 7.55 8.42 Slovakia 5.04 4.81 5.6 5.68 Slovenia 6.02 6.42 6.3 5.88 Spain 4.34 4.08 4.59 4.25 Sweden 8.88 8.67 8.3 8.27 United Kingdom 7.07 6.86 6.54 6.52 EU 1999 3.79 2000 3.87 2001 3.55 2002 3.43 2003 3.61 2004 3.2 4.72 4.01 3.78 3.97 3.65 3.58 5.67 7.83 3.15 6.55 3.91 8.77 5.39 5.95 5.32 6.37 3.71 6.56 6.07 7.81 5.74 9 5.18 5.79 3.39 6.88 5.94 4.28 6 3.38 4.17 5.84 3.42 3.59 5.16 2.97 5.91 5.89 5.7 9.7 5.83 7.01 5.38 8.98 5.34 4.8 9.97 6.69 5.36 9.92 7.89 7.55 5.46 7.17 4.89 5.57 4.57 8.23 9.26 8.27 6.78 4.6 7.85 6.68 5.2 6.57 4.09 9.02 5.72 6.2 5.09 7.92 6.34 4.88 6.48 4.54 10.5 7.29 5.59 6.65 7.66 5.75 4.97 6.39 5.15 7.7 5.47 5.64 4.72 7.37 5.6 6.15 6.61 4.34 7.75 5.08 4.75 5.91 4.68 8.15 4.44 8.02 3.96 8.28 3.87 8.48 4.99 6,28 6,54 6.48 6.42 6.45 6.42 5.69 4.16 Source: Health for All Database (World Health Report), Update January 2006, accessed 07/03/2006 713 Waldhör, T., Vutuc., C., Haidinger, G., Mittlböck, M., Kirchner, L., Wald, M. (2005). Trends in infant mortality in Austria between 1984 and 2002.Wiener klinische Wochenschrift 117 (15-16), pp.548-553 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 232 Table 8.9 Childhood mortality (under 5 years of age) per 1000 children under 5 1960 1970 1980 1990 1995 2000 2003 Austria 43 33 17 9 7 6 5 35 29 15 9 9 6 5 Belgium 36 33 20 12 10 7 5 Cyprus 25 24 19 11 8 5 4 Czech Republic 25 19 10 9 7 5 4 Denmark 52 26 24 17 20 11 9 Estonia 28 16 9 7 4 5 5 Finland 34 24 13 9 7 5 5 France 40 26 16 9 7 6 5 Germany 64 54 23 11 9 6 5 Greece 57 39 26 16 12 9 8 Hungary 36 27 14 9 7 6 6 Ireland 50 33 17 10 7 5 4 Italy 44 26 26 18 20 13 12 Latvia 70 28 22 14 16 12 11 Lithuania 41 26 16 9 6 6 5 Luxembourg 42 32 17 14 11 8 6 Malta 22 15 11 8 6 6 5 Netherlands 70 36 24 19 15 9 7 Poland 112 62 31 15 9 6 5 Portugal 40 29 23 15 12 9 8 Slovakia 45 29 18 9 7 5 4 Slovenia 57 34 16 9 7 5 4 Spain 20 15 9 6 4 4 3 Sweden 23 14 10 7 7 6 United Kingdom 27 Source: Unicef Statistik, http://www.childinfo.org/areas/childmortality/u5data.php, accessed 08/03/2006 Childhood mortality in Austria has declined to the common level of 5 deaths per 1000 children under 5 years of age in Western European countries, having been significantly above average in 1960. During the time period from 1995 to 2004, maternal mortality in Austria ranged between 1.13 (1995) and 6.63 (2001) deaths per thousand live births, not only significantly lower than the EU-average, but also lower than comparable countries such as Germany , the Netherlands or Sweden. While, to some extent, maternal mortality strongly varies in most countries, the EU-average has decreased rather consistently, from 7.36 to 5.71. Table 8.10 Maternal mortality per 1000 live births 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 1.13 4.5 2.38 4.92 1.28 Austria 9.52 5.15 8.6 Belgium 0 0 Cyprus 6.24 7.74 5.52 6.63 10.06 Czech Republic 10.03 5.91 17.74 15.11 13.59 Denmark 51.82 0 15.9 16.44 16.1 Estonia 1.59 3.29 5.06 5.25 3.47 Finland LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 2000 2.56 2001 6.63 2002 2.55 2003 2.6 2004 3.8 0 9.9 36.73 8.82 4.31 7.47 8.19 45.92 5.29 3.06 7.92 5.34 7.69 5.4 30.68 3.53 28.59 12.12 233 France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Poland Portugal Slovakia Slovenia Spain Sweden United Kingdom EU 9.59 5.36 0 15.17 0 3.23 37.05 29.13 18.45 21.68 7.35 12.7 8.4 8.14 5.27 4.4 3.87 6.97 13.21 6.41 4.96 11.4 5.92 3.79 40.44 17.92 0 20.23 12.14 7.71 5.44 4.97 26.61 3.86 5.25 6.55 9.63 6.03 0 20.93 5.68 4.37 42.49 23.8 0 7.38 4.8 5.96 4.23 1.85 2.67 41.25 16.48 7.79 10.91 5.31 3.38 11.01 2.17 3.32 5.37 10.16 5.6 6.94 6.17 3.71 3.38 48.89 18.91 18.57 22.28 11.53 7.58 7.93 8.68 11.2 3.83 7.86 6.84 7.36 7.54 6.45 5.61 23.21 9.48 7.33 5.17 10.67 17.11 5.26 1.13 5.29 10.25 1.83 2.97 24.69 11.71 17.47 0 8.71 7.93 2.5 1.81 22 3.77 4.42 6.77 7.03 7.23 6.06 6.11 7.26 3.68 3.91 5.15 5.48 2.07 25.43 12.68 8.82 2.92 0.97 8.26 8.26 4.24 1.92 7.4 0 5.24 5 19.99 14.3 3.27 50.83 6.91 3.53 5.32 15.64 22.89 4.18 3.28 7.47 0 9.9 5.37 6.99 7.87 0 3.34 4.17 5.98 0 3.99 3.99 7.11 3.87 9.83 16.44 18.34 0 5.15 5,64 5,38 5.29 4.2 0 5.58 4.53 5.71 Source: Health for All Database (World Health Report), Update January 2006, accessed 07/03/2006 More than 76% of all deaths are attributed to cardiovascular diseases and cancer. The remainder of this section focuses on the major risk factors for disease. 8.6.1 Obesity and overweight Diseases and deaths associated with eating habits play an increasingly important role in Austria. According to the nutrition report of 2003, 37% of Austrians are overweight (BMI between 26 and 30), and 9.1% are heavily overweight/obese (BMI>=30). The Austrians’ average consumption of fat is 35-40%, which is significantly above general nutritional recommendations. Compared to the EU-average, more red meat (mostly pork) and sugar is consumed, whereas vegetables and dietary fibres are neglected714. Since Austrians do not appear to assess their weight situation realistically, it would be important to raise awareness of the importance of healthy lifestyles and initiate specific preventive measures. The “Healthy Austria Fund” (Fonds Gesundes Österreich) supports several projects encouraging good health, such as those supporting exercise, nutrition and life conduct. Obesity and overweight prevention projects have been carried out. The fund also addresses the public via media campaigns. On the internet, nutrition-specific information is increasing. However, the quality of this information can often not be judged. 714 BMFG (2005). Public Health in Austria. Vienna LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 234 Figure 8.13 Epidemiology of obesity in Austria per cent (1999) Burgenland Lower Austria Styria Upper Austria Vienna Vorarlberg Carinthia Tyrol Salzburg 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 Source: BMGF, Institute of Nutritional Sciences University of Vienna (2003). Austrian Nutrition Report 2003, page 26 Further activities against obesity are undertaken at a national level (publication of the first obesity report, formation of the plattform "the fat chance“ (die dicke Chance715), publication of the children’s health care plan in August 2004716) as well as by Austrian social insurance funds (health check-ups, standard product health care promotion and prevention, pilot project of the sickness fund of the civil servants for inpatient treatment of severely obese children). The federal states also have started various initiatives. Furthermore a great number of self-help groups throughout Austria are dealing with the issue. There are no reliable statistics on high blood pressure, blood lipids (cholesterol) and diabetes, as it can be assumed that the estimated number of unreported cases is significant. Experts estimate that the number of hypertonics in Austria is 1.5 million (18.3% of the total population) and the number of diabetics is at least 500,000 (6.1% of the total population). Physical inactivity is also an important determinant of health, and is linked to overweight and obesity. Approximately 60% of the Austrian population are more or less physically active (once or twice a week) and 18% can be considered athletic (physical activity more than 3 times a week).717 The Eastern Austrian population shows the lowest degree of awareness for both healthy nutrition and physical activity as means of preventing diseases or maintaining good health (BMGF health report 2004). In the course of an international study (Pan-EU-survey) an activity index for each population was calculated thus making a comparison with international recommendations on the minimum required physical activity possible. They found that 62% of the Austrians older than 15 meet the recommended minimal health care standard (weekly energy use of about 1000 calories achieved by physical activity during which the metabolic rate is 3-6 times higher than in state of inactivity). 38% of the Austrian population are insufficiently active, 16% are totally inactive. Compared to other European countries Austria performs very well (58% do not meet the minimum standard, 32% are totally inactive). Within the EU there is a northsouth divide whereby Austria is one of the more active countries, following in the ranking after Sweden, 715 www.diedickechance.at Federal Minstry of Health and Women, accessed at http://www.bmgf.gv.at/cms/site/attachments/8/8/9/CH0083/CMS1117802910284/kindergesundheitsplan_kurzfass ung.pdf 717 BMGF (2005). Public Health in Austria. Vienna 716 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 235 Finland and Ireland. Favourite leisure activities of the Austrian population are walking, biking, gardening, swimming and hiking. The survey results showed that the EU average for physical inactivity was higher for women and increased with age. Moreover a correlation with education level was demonstrated, adults with compulsory education (Pflichtschulabschluss) are nearly twice as inactive as adults with higher education.718 Figure 8.14 Frequency of weekly physical activity aimed at physical training of 45-64 year-olds in the Austrian population* * Männer: men, Frauen: women, keinmal: not at all, ein- bis zweimal: one or twice, öfter als zweimal: more than twice Häufigkeit der körperlichen Betätigung (mit Schwitzen) pro Woche: Frequency of physical activity (including perspiration) per week Pflichtschule/Lehre: compulsory education/apprenticeship, BMS: school providing lower vocational education AHS/BHS: high school/school providing higher vocational education, Hochschule: university Anteile in %: share in % Source: BMFG Health Report 2004, based on ST.AT-Microcensus-Special Report “Questions about health” 1999 Figure 8.15 Physical Activity in the EU-15 member states Yellow: insufficiently active, red: totally inactive Source: Pan EU Survey in Samitz, G. (2004). ″Physical activity and Public Health – Are Mr. and Mrs Austria sufficiently active? A comparative analysis by Mag. Günther Samitz part 1.″ ASVÖ Newsletter 4 ,pp.4-5 718 Samitz, G. (2004). ″ Physical activity and Public Health – Are Mr. and Mrs Austria sufficiently active? A comparative analysis by Mag. Günther Samitz part 1.″ ASVÖ Newsletter 4 ,pp.4-5 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 236 8.6.2 Tobacco consumption In Austria 29% of the adult population (older than 15 years) smoke.719 The total number of smokers remained static between 1972 and 1997 (the share of men fell (-10%) whilst the proportion of women rose by about the same amount), since it has increased by quite a bit in spite of anti-smoking campaigns and increases in price. The Microcensus in 1997 defined 30% of men and 19% of women as smokers.720 International studies report that the share of adult smokers in Austria has risen form 32% in 1995 to 40% in 2002721. The proportion of men has slightly dropped whilst the proportion of women has demonstrated a strong increase and has nearly caught up with the share of men. In April 2006 minimum prices for cigarettes were introduced by law. So far it is not clear yet if this regulation will withstand inspection of EU authorities. Regarding adolescents smoking at least occasionally, Austria holds the first rank in Europe with 4% of the 11 year olds, 15% of the 13 year-olds and 45% of the 14year-olds. The share of 15 year-olds smoking daily is 20% for boys and 26% for girls which is significantly above the rest of the EU. The following graph depicts the trend in smoking for adolescents between 1990 and 2001. Every year about 14,000 persons die of the consequences of tobacco-related diseases722; about 3,000 persons die of lung cancer whereby 90-96% of them are caused by smoking. Figure 8.16 Percentage of 15-year-old school children smoking daily, by sex723 pink squares…girls, blue diamonds…boys Source: HSBC WHO Study, HSBC factsheet Nr. 1, 2003 719 Groman E., Bayer, P., Kunze, U., Schmeiser-Rieder, A., Schoberberger, R. (2000). ″Analysis of the needs for diagnosis and therapy of tobacco dependence in Austria.″. Wiener Med Wochenschrift 150(6), pp.109-114 in Knopp, A., Sprenger, M., Ertl, B., Starl, T., Püringer, U. (2004). Innovation-Project concept for the future health promotion and prevention, risk factor smoking. Wissenschaftszentrum der Versicherungsanstalt für Eisenbahnen und Bergbau für Gesundheitsförderung und Prävention, Josefhof, Graz 720 Statistics Austria, Microcensus 1997 721 Special Eurobarometer 183/Wave 58.2, Smoking and the Environment, Action and Attitudes, 2003 in Knopp, A., Sprenger, M., Ertl, B., Starl, T., Püringer, U. (2004). Innovation-Project concept for the future health promotion and prevention, risk factor smoking. Wissenschaftszentrum der Versicherungsanstalt für Eisenbahnen und Bergbau für Gesundheitsförderung und Prävention, Josefhof, Graz 722 http://www.einherzfuerwien.at/rauchen.htm, accessed 02/0872006 723 WHO (2003). HSBC Study. HSBC Factsheet No. 1, Smoking, Alcohol, Cannabis, Eds. Federal Ministry of Social Security, Generations and Consumer Protection, Federal Ministry of Education, Science and Culture, Ludwig Boltzmann-Institute for Medicine and Health Sociology. Vienna LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 237 Activities to reduce tobacco consumption724 The Insurance Fund of the Austrian Railway and Mining Industry, the Insurance Fund of the Civil Servants, the regional sickness fund of Upper Austria as well as the occupational fund of the Austria Tabak offer inpatient smoking secession. Numerous sickness funds provide ambulatory smoking secession for their insured (the regional sickness funds of Vienna, Lower Austria, Styria and Upper Austria as well as the health care information centre of the regional sickness fund of Burgenland and Salzburg. Furthermore the insurance fund for civil servants and the occupational fund of Austria Tabak). All federal states boast a big number of places which individuals, who want to give up smoking, can visit. A variety of initiatives to quit smoking have started, an important one being the extension of smoke-free areas. 8.6.3 Alcohol Alcohol is serious problem in Austria. Approximately 5% of the adult population can be considered chronically addicted to alcohol.725 The rate of deaths due to cirrhosis of the liver is the highest in Europe. Over the past 10 years, alcohol abuse by the population has decreased from 18 to 16%. However, the corresponding percentage of women up to 39 years of age has increased significantly. The average amount of alcohol consumed daily by people older than 15 is 30g. (men 51g, women 13g). Significantly greater consumption by men is reflected in accordingly higher potentially alcohol-associated male mortality. Table 8.11 Alcohol consumption in Austria Category 2004 Abstinent 31% Minor alcohol consumption 36% Moderate alcohol consumption 18% Problematic alcohol consumption 12% Extreme alcohol consumption 4% 1993/94 23% 37% 21% 18% n.a. Low alcohol consumption: Men under 24g, Women under 16g of pure alcohol daily (0.3/0.2 L of wine) Moderate alcohol consumption: Men up to 60g, Women up to 40g (0.75 L/0.5L of wine daily) Problematic alcohol consumption: Men over 60g, Women over 40g (0.75 L/0.5L of wine daily) Extreme alcohol consumption: Men over 120g, Women over 80g Source: BMGF (2005). Public Health in Austria, Representative survey for the BMGF by Uhl et al.2005, accessed at www.bmgf.gv.at 82% of 14-17 year-olds stated that they had consumed alcohol in the past month - an absolute peak value in Europe. Only Denmark shows similarly high alcohol consumption in adolescents.726 The overall life expectancy of Austrians is reduced by 2 years, due to a shortened life expectancy by 20 years for persons with high alcohol consumption. 724 Pühringer, U., Knopp, A., Sprenger, M., Ertl, Brigitta, Starl ,Tanja (2004). Innovation-Project concept for the future health promotion and prevention, risk factor smoking. Versicherungsanstalt für Eisenbahnen und Bergbau Wissenschaftszentrum 725 BMGF health report 2004 726 BMGF Public Health in Austria 2005 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 238 Table 8.12 Abuse of alcohol and alcoholism in Austria (whole population) Missbraucher und Alkoholkranke nach Geschlecht in Zahlen (und Prozent) Alcohol diseased Alcohol abusers (excl. Alcohol diseased) Alcohol ambusers and alcohol-diseased 90,000 (27%) 280,000 (39%) 370,000 (35%) Men 245,000 (73%) 444,000 (61%) 685,000 (65%) Total 335,000 (100 %) 720,000 (100%) 1,055,000 (100%) Women Source: Repräsentativstudie Uhl et al., 2004, abgeruf en unter: Fonds Gesundes Österreich, http://w w w .f goe.org/der-fonds/inf os/plonearticle.2006-05-29.8117585778 am 30.06.06 Figure 8.17 Alcohol intoxication of adolescents Repeated alcohol intoxication of Austrian adolescents 15-year-old boys 46% 15-year-old girls 30% 13-year-old boys 13-year-old girls 0% 16% 9% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% Source: Dür and Hutter (1997 and 2001). Health Behavior of School-Aged Children (HBSC).Vienna. accessed at the Healthy Austria Fund at http://www.fgoe.org/der-fonds/infos/plonearticle.2006-05-29.8117585778 on 30/0672006 8.6.4 Poverty and health International studies show that mortality and morbidity are significantly higher in lower social classes than for individuals of higher socio-economic status. Presumably, this applies to Austria as well. Exact figures and information on class-specific differences concerning health risks, morbidity and mortality are rare. Individuals whose weighted per capita income lies below the threshold level of 60% of the average Austrian per capita income are endangered by poverty. People additionally facing rigorous restrictions in major areas of life, such as extensive arrears of rent and heating costs or lack the financial means to invite someone to their homes at least once a month are considered acutely or manifestly poor. Those most endangered by poverty are male and female workers, farmers and unemployed persons. Women are generally more affected than men. As in all European countries, the number of “working poor” whose household expenses exceed the gross individual income is increasing continuously.727 727 Pochobradsky, E., Habl, C., Schleicher, B., Hlava, A. (2002). Social inequality and health care. Study commissioned by the Federal Ministry of Health and Women. Vienna. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 239 Results from the EU-SILC March 2006-06-25 According to the newest data (March 2006) from the EU-SILC (Statistics on Income and Living Conditions), the weighted per capita income of a one-person household in Austria is €16.969 per year. That corresponds to an amount of €1.414 per month. The population quarter with the lowest income level of the Austrian population disposes of less than €12,868 per year. In contrast, the richest population quarter has an annual income of at least €22.404. According to the European standard, the so-called poverty threshold is 60% of the average income. People with less than €10.182 per year at their disposal (or €848 per month) are considered to be endangered by poverty. In 2004, approximately 1,030,000 people in Austria were concerned, comprising 13% of the population. The risk of poverty is 11% for persons born in Austria, and 23% for immigrants who have been granted Austrian citizenship.728 Male and female immigrants run the highest risk of poverty, at 28%. The risk of poverty for persons who have only completed compulsory education is 18%. While the risk of poverty for the employed is only 8%, the figures are significantly higher for the unemployed. • • • • Male and female retired persons 13% Individuals undergoing education 19% Male and female homemakers 22% Unemployed persons 32% The number of employed persons of working age whose households are below the poverty threshold is approximately 250,000. The so-called “working poor” constitute almost half of all persons endangered by poverty in this age group. Women are particularly threatened by poverty. Women’s lower labour force as well as lower incomes have an impact on the risk of poverty. Persons living in households where the basic income is provided by women are threatened by poverty almost twice as often (19%) as people living in households where men provide the major share of income. The risk of poverty for single parents with only one income lies above average, at 24%. Single households are generally at a higher risk of experiencing poverty, the probability of living in poverty being 25% for women who are clearly more frequently endangered by poverty than male singles (16%). 23% of families with 3 or more children are endangered by poverty. Living in a household with more people involves a risk of poverty that is below average, provided the number of income providers is high. In families with 3 or more children and families with small children, there is an increase of poverty, particularly when the woman is not working. 6% of the Austrian population are manifestly poor. 23% of those endangered by poverty cannot afford basic necessities such as sufficient heating for their homes. In 6% of the population, low income is combined with a low standard of living, consequently classifying them as poor by definition. In principle (theoretically), poor people do not receive a lower quality of care by the Austrian health system than wealthier people. The social security system provides access to an extensive health care package for about 98% of the population. However, a correlation between low income, poorer subjective health and modified utilization of health care can be shown in Austria as well729. In Microcensus surveys, members of the “underclass” assess their state of health as significantly worse, are sick more often and take medications more frequently than members of higher social classes. Additionally, they consult general practitioners more frequently, but rarely consult specialists and dentists. The access to ambulatory health care entails 728 Persons who have been granted Austrian citizenship and did not have EU- or EFTA citizenship before Freidl, W., Stronegger, W.J., Rásky, É., Neuhold.C.(2001). “Associations of income with self-reported ill-health and health resources in a rural community sample of Austria “ Sozial- und Präventivmedizin 46, pp. 106-114 729 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 240 longer travel times and waiting periods.730 Those who are socially weaker take less advantage of sick leaves and have check-ups less frequently, for fear of losing their jobs, and consistently receive prescriptions for cheaper medications.731 However, in contrast to several European countries, where the gap between socioeconomic classes has even increased throughout the past decades, the situation in Austria has improved at least marginally during the 1990s. A positive connection between the standard of living and life expectancy in Austria has been shown: there is a strong correlation between the proportion of living category D (sub-standard) in urban and rural districts and life expectancy. For a proportion of 2.5%, the life expectancy is approximately 77 years. For 16%, it is only slightly over 75 years. Particularly in Austria, remarkable statistical correlations between mortality caused by malignant neoplasms of the respiratory organs and living conditions have become apparent.732 8.6.5 Socio-economic status and health Morbidity, measured in the number of episodes of illness and the duration of the episodes, decreases with a higher level of education. For men a more or less linear decrease was experienced with the highest morbidity of men having lower secondary education in comparison to the lowest morbidity of university graduates. For women, female university graduates are an exception, displaying the second highest level or morbidity, otherwise morbidity also falls with higher levels of education.733 Unemployed feature a higher morbidity than employed. According to social insurance data unemployed had 33 days of sickness whereas wage and salary earners had only 13 days. Employed men have more days of sickness whereas unemployed women are sick more often (see following diagram). Data from the household survey in 1999 (micro-census) shows a smaller difference between unemployed and employed (23 vs. 9.3 days of sickness). Based on these surveys women have in general more episodes of illness, also in the group of employed. The strong increase in morbidity for the unemployed in the 90ies originates from a larger share of older citizens among the unemployed as well as the increasing morbidity rates of the population older than 30. 730 Hofmarcher, M., Röhrling, G., Riedel, M. (2003). ″Age structure and health expenditure: Are the EU-countries prepared for the EU-health-politics? Focus: Diagnosis poverty?″ Health System Watch III, pp. 10-20, supplement to the journal of Austrian Social Insurance, Soziale Sicherheit 731 Habl, C. (2004). ″Options for reducing social inequalites in health care.″ WISO 2, pp. 93-104 732 Source: Survey Women and Poverty 733 Biffl G. (2004). Health and Employment Status. The Case of Austria. WIFO Working Papers 219, pp. 1-25 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 241 Figure 8.18 Morbidity rate of employed and unemployed by gender Source: Biffl G. (2004). Health and Employment Status. The Case of Austria. WIFO Working Papers 219, pp. 1-25 As already mentioned before, the risk of poverty is situated at 11% for persons born in Austria, and at 23% for immigrants who have been granted Austrian citizenship. Male and female immigrants run the highest risk of poverty, at 28%.734 An analysis performed by the Hauptverband735 shows that the per capita cost for physician services, pharmaceuticals and dental care is lower for consumers of services with foreign citizenship of all ages compared to the per capita cost of consumers of services with Austrian citizenship. Especially for insured older than 55 years there is a remarkable difference between the two groups. For more details see Appendix 18. 8.6.6 Evidence on measures of mortality amenable to medical intervention: variation across regions736 The WHO European Health Report 2005737 published figures for mortality amenable to primary or secondary prevention: average deaths per 100,000 population, figures for Austria and the UK are given in the table below (Table 8.13). Table 8.13 Mortality rates of diseases amenable to prevention (rates per 100,000 population, all ages) Mortality amenable to primary prevention Mortality amenable to secondary prevention Cancer of the Cancer of the Motor vehicle traffic injurya Cerebro vascular disease Chronic liver disease liver lung skin breast Cervix Other parts of the uterus 2.5 Upper airway and digestive tract 5.6 Austria 10.2 9.2 13.8 17.8 1.5 15.3 2.0 2.2 UK 5.7 10.7 6.7 0.8 5.0 17.2 1.4 20.6 2.7 1.2 734 Results from the EU-SILC, see Statistics Austria at www.statistik.at Grillitsch (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). 23 June 2006 via email 736 Univ.-Prof. Dr. Anita Rieder, Kitty Lawrence BEng. 737 WHO European Health Report 2005, available at http://www.who.dk/document/e87325.pdf 735 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 242 Analysis of amenable mortality, i.e. deaths that would be preventable if all the relevant knowledge, services and resources of the health system and society were optimally applied can address how much health systems specifically contribute to health. The primary prevention figures could show the impact of interventions to reduce exposure to lifestyle and occupational risk factors. Secondary prevention figures comprise impact of screening, early detection, diagnosis and treatment. Table 8.14 shows the potential number of lost years of life (per 100,000) of under 70 year olds by cause of death, in Austria for 1970 and 2000738. In Austria in recent years a number of health reports have been published, which have for the first time compiled all available data on various topics, including diabetes, obesity, allergy and neuropathic pain. These have been used as sources of information on mortality. Table 8.14 Potential number of life years lost (per 100,000) of under 70 year olds Women Cause of death Men 1970 2000 1970 2000 Infectious diseases 125,5 10,3 212,3 30,0 Malignant growths 1.338,0 816,9 1.517,0 1.003,7 Bowel cancer 130,8 65,9 167,8 83,6 Lung cancer 55,0 113,9 384,1 259,9 Breast cancer 255,0 200,7 - - Cervical cancer 87,0 22,8 - - Prostate cancer - - 25,1 24,1 Cardiovascular System 863,0 389,2 1.990,0 967,2 Ischaemic heart diseases 243,6 119,5 1.140,2 529,2 Acute myocardial infarction 171,8* 87,9 760,6* 383,2 Cerebrovascular diseases 285,4 94,7 459,0 140,2 Variations across regions Regional differences have been determined in, for example, mortality due to cardiovascular diseases CVD mortality • • Statistical Information on health care in Vienna 2000/2002 (Statistische Mitteilungen zur Gesundheit in Wien 2000/2002) – includes chapter on epidemiology covering mortality in Austria and Vienna due to cardiovascular diseases. Mortality - heart disease – across federal states – across districts of Vienna: further information (various graphs) available on differences in morbidity and mortality comparing Vienna with the other federal states and the districts in Vienna in general there appears to be an east west gradient with mortality being higher in the western regions. See Figure 8.19 below. 738 City of Vienna. Life expectancy and mortality in Vienna. 2003 (Stadt Wien. Lebenserwartung und Mortalität in Wien. 2003) LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 243 For further information on the “big city factor” analysis see Appendix 19 (slides from a presentation held by Univ.-Prof. Dr. Rieder at the Hauptverband 22 March 2004) and the Viennese report on Myocardial infarction 2004 (Wiener Herzinfarktbericht 2004) – Mortality data relating to cardiovascular disease Figure 8.19 Ischemic heart disease mortality of under 75 year olds 1990 - 1999 by federal state and sex 100 = mortality in Austria 133 137,3 Vienna 98,9 104,2 Burgenland 100 100,7 Lower Aust. 93 94,3 Styria 90,5 85,4 Upper Aust. Men Women 87,9 80,2 Tyrol 85,7 78,9 Vorarlberg Carinthia 73,4 82,6 80 79,3 Salzburg 0 100 Source: Statistische Mitteilungen zur Gesundheit in Wien 2000/2 Figure 8.20 Mortality of <75 year old men due to cardiovascular disease in Vienna, by district 149,1 140,6 139,3 137,4 131,2 130,7 130,6 130,5 130,1 130 128,6 126,7 124 123,4 20 15 11 10 3 14 12 5 16 21 22 7 9 2 17 6 13 23 4 8 18 19 1 92,7 50 116,2 111,4 110,6 109,7 105,1 104,6 102,9 102,4 100 100 = mortality in Austria 150 Source: Statistische Mitteilungen zur Gesundheit in Wien 2000/2 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 244 Figure 8.21 Mortality of <75 year old women due to cardiovascular disease in Vienna, by district 15 12 20 11 16 10 2 5 14 17 21 22 3 6 7 13 9 8 1 23 19 4 18 143,8 142,8 138,2 137,8 136,6 132,6 131,2 129,4 128,9 128,7 126,9 123,8 121,9 114,1 106,8 106,1 100,6 100,2 97,3 95,3 94,5 94 91,8 50 100 100 = mortality in Austria 150 Source: Statistische Mitteilungen zur Gesundheit in Wien 2000/2 Maternal mortality Shortcomings of official registrations of maternal deaths, thus maternal mortality cannot be seen as a reliable basis for health policy decisions, between 1980 and 1998 119 maternal deaths were registered at Statistics Austria, confidential enquiries showed 191 maternal deaths.739 Infant mortality Austria has one of the lowest infant mortality rates in Europe. The mortality rate has been fairly static between 1999 and 2002, a further reduction cannot be achieved by advances in medicine alone. It will be a challenge for public health, politics, physicians and society to reduce well known risk factors, such as alcohol abuse, heavy overweight and smoking during pregnancy.740 Cancer Cancer mortality decreased between 1970 and 1996, the decrease in total cancer mortality is promoted by three tumour sites (the leading causes of cancer in 1970), stomach cancer, followed by colorectal cancer in women and lung cancer in men. The observed changes in mortality are primarily related to changing incidence and early detection, rather than improvements in treatment.741 Analysis of cancer mortality 1970-2002, observed changes (decreasing rates) are primarily related to changes in incidence and in the last decade to improved treatment and early detection, but neither of these contributions can be quantified.742 Examination of the prevalence (Self-reported) of cervical cancer screening and impact on cancer mortality show that mortality has nearly been halved between 1980 and 1996, most of its reduction must be attributed 739 Karimian-Teherani, D., Haidinger, G., Waldhoer, T., Beck, A., Vutuc, C. (2002). ”Underreporting of direct and indirect obstetrical deaths in Austria 1980-1998.” Acta Obstetricia et Gynecologica Scandinavica 81:4, pp.323-327 740 Waldhör, T., Vutuc., C., Haidinger, G., Mittlböck, M., Kirchner, L., Wald, M. (2005). Trends in infant mortality in Austria between 1984 and 2002.Wiener klinische Wochenschrift 117 (15-16), pp.548-553 741 Vutuc, C., Waldhör, T., Haidinger, G. Ahmad, F., Miksche, M. (1999). ”The burden of cancer in Austria” Eur J Cancer Prev 8 (1), pp. 49-55 742 Vutuc, C., Waldhoer, T., Haidinger, G.(2004). ”Cancer mortality in Austria: 1970-2002.” Wien klin Wochenschrift 116, pp. 19-20 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 245 to the screening activities in the 1970s and a further decrease as a result of the expanded screening activities in the 1980s.743 Survival of women with breast cancer in Austria by age, stage and period of diagnosis show between 199397 age –adjusted mortality decreased overall by 3.3%, it is concluded that treatment improvements, which are accessible to all patients countrywide due to the compulsory state insurance system, may or impact on mortality and survival, opportunistic screening to some extent contributed to some extend beginning in the early 1990s.744 Lung cancer mortality in Austria reached its peak in 1973 and decreased gradually after a plateau by 23%. As far as women are concerned, the risk of dying from lung cancer has risen dramatically for the last 20 years. Nowadays Austria has to cope with an increasing number of children and adolescents (especially females) starting smoking very early. Diabetes In Austria in 2002 2028 deaths (874 men and 1154 women) were recorded with the diagnosis of diabetes mellitus (E10-14in accordance with ICD10) (see figure 8.22).745 Altogether 76 131 Austrians died in 2002. The deaths due to diabetes mellitus, therefore make up 2.7% of all deaths (2.5% of deaths amongst men and 2.8% of deaths amongst women). With the exception of the over 75’s the number of deaths was higher amongst men. Looking in more detail at the individual federal states the most deaths due to diabetes were registered in the eastern regions of Lower Austria, Vienna, and Styria, see Figure 8.22. Figure 8.22 Number of deaths in Austria in 2002 with the diagnosis Diabetes Mellitus (E10-14 according to ICD 10) by sex and federal state Source: own calculations using data from: Statistics Austria in the Austrian Diabetes Report 2004 Looking at the age standardised death rates for the various federal states in can be seen that, with the exception of Vorarlberg, the death rates amongst men are higher than those of women. Furthermore death rates due to diabetes are highest in Vienna, Lower Austria, Burgenland and Styria and are lowest in the western states of the Tyrol, Salzburg, and Vorarlberg, see Figure 8.23. 743 Vutuc C, Haidinger G, Waldhör T, Ahmad F, Breitenecker G. (1999). ”Prevalence of selfreported cervical cancer screening and impact on cervical cancer mortality in Austria.” Wien Klin Wochenschr. 111, pp. 354–359. 744 Vutuc, C., Waldhoer, T., Klimont, J., Haidinger, G., Jakesz, R. Kubista, E. , Zielinski, C. (2002). ”Survival of women with breast cancer in Austria by age, stage and period of diagnosis.” Wien Klin Wochenschr. 114, pp.438-42 745 Austrian Diabetes Report 2004 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 246 Figure 8.23 Number of deaths in Austria in 2002 with the diagnosis Diabetes Mellitus (E10-14 according to ICD 10) by sex and federal state standardised rates per 100 000 living and of the same sex total 20 Men Women 17,84 16,46 15,11 15 12,42 14,7 13,89 13,05 16,25 14,78 14,45 13,84 13,46 12,56 13,09 11,87 11,27 10,2 11,74 11,43 10,26 9,55 10 13,41 9,12 9,49 8,69 7,85 7,63 9,14 7,72 5,42 V ie nn a V or ar lb er g T yr ol S ty ria S al zb ur g A us t. U pp er Lo w .A us t. C ar in th ia A us tri a 0 B ur ge nl an d 5 Source: own calculations using data from: Statistik Austria in the Austrian Diabetes Report 2004 It must be noted, however, that the interpretation of the Austrian cause of death statistics is afflicted with many limitations, precisely with regards diabetes mellitus, and as such mortality rates are likely to be underestimated: In the cause of death statistics those deaths with the diagnosis diabetes mellitus are recorded on the death certificate when it is the underlying disease in a chain of illnesses. This underlying disease is, however, often not known to the doctor present at the time of death and is as such not recorded on the death certificate. Many deaths with underlying diabetes mellitus are, therefore, not documented as diabetes deaths. A further important limitation of the cause of death statistics is that omission of cardiovascular diseases as a complication of diabetes. These are not provided for in the ICD 10 and are therefore not recorded in the cause of death statistics. For more information on mortality due to diabetes in Austria see Appendix 20 and the Austrian Diabetes Report 2004.746 8.6.7 Factors contributing to changes in health status747 Some examples of factors that contribute to observed changes in health status include: • • • • Lung cancer is increasing in women - see Appendix 21 – is considered to be linked with smoking. Diabetes report (Diabetesbericht) – shows an increase in the incidence of diabetes The acute myocardial infarction in Vienna – an analysis from 2002 (Der akute Herzinfarkt in Wien – eine Analyse aus dem Jahr 2002) More on reduction of mortality due to screening – see section on prevention and screening programs further on Obesity The first Austrian Obesity Report was published in August 2006. Obesity is associated with a higher morbidity and mortality. Obesity related diseases and disorders include diabetes mellitus type 2, diseases of the gallbladder, insulin resistance, breathlessness, sleep apnoea (relative risk > 3), cardiovascular diseases, osteoarthritis of the knee, hyperuric aemia, gout (relative risk 2 – 3), cancer of the breast, endometrium and 746 747 Download available at www.bmgf.gv.at Univ.-Prof. Dr. Anita Rieder, Kitty Lawrence BEng. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 247 colon, disturbances of the sexual hormones, polycystic ovary syndrome, back pain, increased risk of complications during surgery, and foetal defects (relative risk 1 – 2). In 2004 5,839 cases were documented with a primary discharge diagnosis of obesity from Austrian hospitals, this is equivalent to a rate of 71 per 100,000 inhabitants of the same sex and age. Almost two thirds of these discharge cases (3,740) were women, the peak age being lower than that for the prevalences of obesity. The overall duration of stay was 73,400 days, equivalent to 12.6 days per case (15.9 for men and 10.7 for women). The actual situation is vastly underestimated since obesity is seldom documented as the primary discharge diagnosis. A special analysis of the hospital discharge statistics of the Viennese Hospital Network allows certain conclusions to be drawn with regards the frequency of obesity related co-morbidities in Austria, causalities could however not be deduced: In 2005 obesity was most frequently registered as a secondary diagnosis for the primary diagnosis group of circulatory disorders (29%), and here above all with ischemic heart disease (12% of all cases). 13% of discharge cases with obesity as the secondary diagnosis had a primary diagnosis of diseases of the musculoskeletal system and connective tissue, 11% had a primary diagnosis of diseases of the digestive system. For both sexes the frequency of occurrence of diabetes mellitus is highest amongst the obese compared to over and normal weight persons. In 1995 it was estimated that 12.5 per 100,000 new cancer cases amongst men and 14.9 per 100,000 amongst women were associated with overweight and obesity. Obese persons have a significantly higher risk for various forms of cancer (Men: colon, rectum, pancreas; women: uterus, non-Hodgkin-lymphoma, breast in women > 65 years). Obesity increases mortality and shortens life expectancy, especially of younger people. An extremely obese young person (20 – 30 years, BMI > 45 kg/m2) probably loses 13 (man) or 8 (woman) life years as a consequence of obesity. Overweight 40 year olds lose 3 life years, obese persons of the same age 6 – 7 years. Table 8.15 Inpatient cases treated with main diagnosis of obesity (E66 according to ICD-10) or localised obesity (E65) by federal state, Austria, 2004 Federal State Lower Austria Vienna Upper Austria Styria Tyrol Carinthia Salzburg Vorarlberg Burgenland unassigned Total Males Females 623 384 295 284 124 112 93 71 100 13 2.099 Total 787 641 592 421 442 264 236 254 84 19 3.740 1.410 1.025 887 705 566 376 329 325 184 32 5.839 Source: Statistics Austria, own calculations Table 8.16 Inpatient cases treated with main diagnosis of obesity (E66 according to ICD-10) or localised obesity (E65) by federal state, Austria, 2004 Federal State Males Females Total Vorarlberg 40 140 90 Lower Austria 81 98 90 Tyrol 37 125 82 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 248 Carinthia Burgenland Upper Austria Vienna Salzburg Styria Total 41 74 43 50 37 49 53 91 59 83 76 87 69 89 67 66 64 64 63 59 71 Source: Statistics Austria, own calculations Notes: Rates per 100.000 inhabitants of the same sex and federal state. For more information see the Austrian Obesity Report 2006748. According to available data an increasing trend in prevalence of obesity can be observed in Austria: In the adult population obesity rose by 7% from 8.5% to 9.1% between 1991 and 1999 (self reported). Measured data from Vorarlberg, a region traditionally having a low prevalence of obesity, show an increase in prevalence of obesity of 14% for men (from 8.5% to 9.7%) and 17% for women (from 11.7% to 13.7%), within the same time frame. In 1991 3.3 % of recruits to the Austrian federal armed forces were obese, in 2002 5.3% were obese (an increase of 61%). International data point out that there are practically no countries in which the prevalence of obesity is not rising. Even in countries with a traditionally low prevalence, as well as, in many so called developing countries, an increasing trend in prevalence of obesity has been observed, above all in the echelons of society who have embraced a western lifestyle. A further increase in prevalence of obesity has been predicted for the future, at the current rate of increase half the adult population will have a BMI > 30 kg/m2 by the year 2040. 8.6.8 Are these factors related to health care, public health, health policy, lifestyle or other aspects It is to be expected that all of the above factors influence health status. In the case of the effect of altering lifestyle factors international studies are used as indicators of the possible successes of implementing preventive lifestyle measures. In the case of coronary heart disease the BMJ published a paper modelling the decline in CHD deaths in England and Wales 1981-2000: comparing contributions from primary and secondary prevention.749 For details see Appendix 22. Health reports have shown increasing trends in various risk factors. As outlined in 8.3.2 above, obesity plays a major role in the health of Austrians750 (Österreichischer Adipositasbericht, 2006). The 1st Austrian Allergy Report751 has also compiled all available data on allergies in Austria. From the evaluation of data from military health examinations carried out for all 18year old men eligible for national service between 1986 to 2005 it was possible to gain an idea of the trends. These data showed that the prevalence of all allergies is increasing amongst 18-year old men eligible for national service. The Viennese health and social survey (Wiener Gesundheits- und Sozialsurvey) from which data was also presented in the Allergy Report, lists smoking, passive smoking and environmental pollution as possible influencing factors leading to a worsening of allergies, see Tables 8.17 and 8.18. 748 www.alternmitzukunft.at Unal, B., Chritchley, J.A., Capewell, S. (2005). ” Modelling the decline in coronary heart disease deaths in England and Wales, 1981-2000: comparing contributions from primary prevention and secondary prevention.” BMJ 331, pp. 614-619 750 Erster Österreichischer Adipositasbericht 2006, accessed at: http://www.welldone.at/upload/3031_AMZ_Adipositas_3108_final.pdf 751 downloadable from www.alternmitzukunft.at 749 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 249 Table 8.17 Aggravation of allergic rhinitis through the environment Worsening of allergy related cold through: Smoking Passive smoking Environmental pollution yes No 5,3 18,4 20,0 33,3 50,7 50,7 Not applicable (don’t smoke) 43,1 8,0 4,5 Don’t know No response 8,8 13,1 15,1 9,6 9,8 9,8 Don’t know No response 9,2 11,2 15,3 16,3 16,3 15,3 Source: Wiener Gesundheits- und Sozialsurvey, own calculations Table 8.18 Aggravation of Asthma through the environment Worsening of asthma through: Smoking Passive smoking Environmental pollution yes No 22,4 32,7 34,7 11,2 32,7 32,7 Not applicable (don’t smoke) 40,8 7,1 2,0 Source: Wiener Gesundheits- und Sozialsurvey, own calculations It was also found that children whose mothers smoked during pregnancy had a high risk for developing allergic rhinitis. A potential protective factor, on the other hand, was growing up on a farm. Other factors are mentioned below: • • • • According to Kalla K, et al. (2006) implementation of guidelines improves the standard of care: A significant improvement in clinical outcomes, with respect to in-hospital mortality, was associated with implementation of guidelines.752 Could be linked with lack of knowledge (e.g. of own blood pressure).753 Survival of women with breast cancer in Austria by age, stage and period of diagnosis show between 1993-97 age –adjusted mortality decreased overall by 3.3%, it is concluded that treatment improvements, which are accessible to all patients countrywide due to the compulsory state insurance system, major or impact on mortality and survival, opportunistic screening to some extent contributed to some extend beginning in the early 1990s.754 In 1997, an activity-based hospital financing system (so called LKF-system) was implemented in Austria. This fundamental change was a switch from a reimbursement system to a purchasing system combined with a fixed budget. This could have consequences for data such as hospital mortality data and discharge statistics. Overall factors having the most influence on the health of Austrians appear to be lifestyle related. The Austrian Health Report 2004755 lists following factors: • • Overweight - Between 1991 and 1999 the number of overweight persons aged over 15 years (Body- Mass-Index - BMI - between 26 and 30) has risen. In the same period the share of massively overweight persons (BMI over 30) also rose. Hypertension and lack of awareness - In the sample census on health of 1991, approximately 8.3% of the respondents (Austrians over 15) indicated that they suffered from hypertension (i.e. around 752 Kalla, K., Christ, G., Karnik, R. et al. (2006). ” Implementation of Guidelines Improves the Standard of Care. The Viennese Registry on Reperfusion Strategies in ST-Elevation Myocardial Infarction (Vienna STEMI Registry).” Circulation 113 (20), pp. 2398-2405 753 Fodor, J.G., Lietava, J., Rieder, A., et al. (2004). ” Work-site hypertension prevalence and control in three Central European Countries.” Journal of Human Hypertension 18 (8), pp.581-585 754 Vutuc, C., Waldhoer, T., Klimont, J., Haidinger, G., Jakesz, R. Kubista, E. , Zielinski, C. (2002). ”Survival of women with breast cancer in Austria by age, stage and period of diagnosis.” Wien Klin Wochenschr. 114, pp.43842 755 Download available at www.bmgf.gv.at LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 250 • • • 530,000 people), with women more strongly affected than men (8.8% v. 7.7%). Here the number of incorrect statements is likely to be high, as according to experts, Austria has approximately 1.5 million hypertension patients. Nutrition - Only around 37% of the respondents (sample census 1991) reported having a healthy diet, with women of any age group attaching more importance to healthy nutrition than men. The 2003 Austrian Report on Nutrition gives a favourable assessment of the trends regarding food eaten, in particular the rise in use of vegetables, fruit and fish was generally regarded as positive. However, it also showed that Austrians still eat too much rich food and that total fat intake is too high. Lack of exercise – Only around 37% of the population pursue exercise or practice sports to preserve health or to prevent diseases. Smoking - 30% of the population are daily cigarette smokers. The share of male smokers (36%) is significantly higher than the share of women smoking (27%). However, the share and number of female smokers (in particular young people) are rising. 8.7 Health targets in Austria756 Health targets have been defined or at least discussed in one way or the other in various European countries as a tool to aid the development and monitoring of health policies.757 Thus, health targets are meant to serve as steering instruments but should also be used to measure results. 8.7.1 National health targets The discussion on targets in health care was revived in 2002. This is documented in the conference report of the 3rd Austrian health care conference.758 At that occasion thoughts on the development of a national health care plan were presented which however did not come into effect at that time. The government programme for the XXII legislative period envisaged the formulation of Austrian health care targets and set up a list of certain activities planned in the health care sector. These activities were entirely of administrative and structural sorts and not related to the health care status of the population. The Austrian health care conference was recorded to be a medium for efficient discussions between all in charge in order to achieve better coordination in the area of health care. The federal Minister of Health and Women, Maria RauchKallat presented the “health care goals 2010” on the occasion of the health care conference 2003. These goals consist of three general objectives or principles and the definition of five activity areas.759 Health care goals include: - Best quality of medical care provided Clear, efficient structures Expenses are realigned with income Five fields of activity: - Health promotion Quality assurance Innovations Structures Finances 756 Mag. Daniel Hentschel MSc. Marinker, M (2002). Health targets in Europe: polity, progress and promise. London: BMJ Publishing Group. 758 BMGF (2002).Health care conference. accessed at http://www.bmgf.gv.at/cms/site/attachments/3/5/8/CH0011/CMS1038854676005/gesundheitskonferenz_2002.pdf 759 Rauch-Kallat, M. (BMGF) (2003). Health Care Targets 2010. Presentation given November 10, 2003 (Austrian Health Care Conference), accessed at www.bmgf.gv.at 757 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 251 In addition the following “health care dialogues” were established as a participative method for the further development and specification of goals:760 - Consumer orientation in the health care sector Health promotion Public Health / Food safety Liberty vs. addiction Quality assurance in health care Children’s health care plan Action programme hospice Health care professions Management of pharmaceuticals Digitalisation in health care Health care insurance Health care agencies In the course of the health care reform in 2005 three health targets were defined:761 - Reduction of cardiovascular mortality by 40% until 2020 (for the population younger than 65 years) Reduction of the prevalence of carcinomas by 15% Reduction of the prevalence of diabetes by 20% In the agreement according to article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act, which was signed by the Federation and the federal states in 2005 the following goals were defined:762 - Support measures for health promotion Introduce a compulsory quality system for the Austrian health care system which will improve efficiency. This should be continuously developed further. Create the requirements for an effective and efficient use of information technology in health care Achieve integrated and co-ordinated planning and steering of all areas in health care Improve interface management between the institutions providing health care services The Austrian People’s Party (Österreichische Volkspartei, ÖVP) took up the topic of health targets in a brochure763, but didn’t pursue it with great emphasis. In August 2006 the federal minister of health, Maria Rauch-Kallat presented the initiative „Austria: Health Care World Champion 2010“ in the course of which ten health care targets for the year 2010 were defined. The initiative is, according to the federal minister, aimed at “mobilising all actors in the health care system as well as the entire Austrian population to make the Austrian health care system the best health care system and the Austrian population the healthiest” worldwide764. The ten targets are the following:765 1. 2. 3. Reduction of people younger than 65 years dying of cardiovascular disease by 20% Reduction of the number of people dying because of cancer by up to 7% Reduction of the amount of damages caused by diabetes by about 1/3 760 Hofmarcher, M., Kraus, M., Riedel, M. (2004). Health targets and indicators as steering instrument of social health insurance, Project report. Commissioned by the Hauptvebrand der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger. Institute of Advanced Studies. Vienna 761 Hofmarcher, M., Rack, H.M. (2006). Health Care Systems in Transition. Austria. Copenhagen, World Health Organisation on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 762 Article 15a of the Federal Constitution, Preamble 763 Austrian Peoples’ Party (OEVP) (2006). Plant ideas, harvest future, perspective for Austria – materials for the future talks 2006. brochure, accessed at http://www.oevp.at/loadcontrol.aspx?type=download&fstep=2&f=677&bi=19 764 Bundesministerium für Gesundheit und Frauen, www.gesundheitsweltmeister.at 765 Further information can be found on the website of the initiative www.gesundheitsweltmeister.at. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 252 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. Containment of adiposity Reduction of communicable diseases Reduction of the number of accidents by 25% Improvement of psychosocial well-being Reduce tobacco consumption considerably Reduce alcohol consumption considerably Improve the status of dental care Further information can be found on the website of the project, www.gesundheitsweltmeister.at. 8.7.2 Regional health care goals On the regional level the regional sickness funds of the federal states of Upper Austria (OÖGKK), Lower Austria (NÖGKK) and Styria (STGKK) have developed health care targets766 (the goals of the OÖGKK and the NÖGKK are in the Appendix 23). Political practicability and effectiveness of health care targets depends strongly on the existence of clear, qualitative indicators. To be able to assess the degree of concretisation of health care targets Czypionka et al. differentiate between the following levels of classification:767 - Goals: general description of what is to be achieved in the long term, based on values and principles Objectives: more specific description of how a target can be reached, can partly be achieved within a planning period Qualitative Target: more specific than an objective, is to be achieved by a certain deadline Quantitative Target: includes a mechanism for evaluation with measurable indicators , designed to monitor progress or development Based on this classification the authors assign the targets which were published by the Ministry of Health and Women solely to the “goals” category. Only 5 areas of activity are defined as well as 3 very general health targets from which it is not possible to derive quantifiable indicators related to the health care status. The 10 health care targets of the regional sickness fund of Upper Austria however are qualified as tangible “quantitative targets”. It can be seen in Appendix 23 that these goals effectively specify not only the quantitative extent of aspired changes (e.g. reduction of consequences of diabetes by 10%) but also the time frame (e.g. by the year 2010). The targets of the regional sickness fund of Lower Austria are partially precisely specified (20% less individuals suffering from alcohol related diseases by the year 2010), and partially rather vague (e.g. higher usage of preventive services). 8.7.3 Targets in Social Insurance Beginning with the year 2000 Austrian social insurance funds have to define short- and medium term goals related to health politics and social politics. These have to be harmonised with politics. Social insurance uses the Balanced Scorecard method, a target steering instrument. Innovation projects were defined in the areas of hospital funding, controlling of services, controlling of contributions, questions related to provision of dental services and psychotherapy, disease management, health promotion, evidence-based reorganisation of preventive services, development of new tariff models for transportation, quality development and development of the learning organisation. 766 Probst, J.(2005). Starting position and visions for the Austrian health care sytem. In: Sprenger, M. Eds. (2005). Public Health in Austria und Europe, Lengerich, Pabst Science Publishers. 767 Czypionka , T., Kraus, M., Riedel, M.., Röhrling, G. (2005). “Focus: Health targets: wide-spread or a mere isolated case in Europe?" Health System Watch IV, supplement of the Austrian journal of social insurance, Soziale Sicherheit, pp.8-14 LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 253 Goals of Social insurance 2006 The catalogue of goals of Austrian social insurance for 2006 defines 21 precise targets, which are subdivided into the areas “continuous development and learning”, “optimised processes”, “consolidation of finances” as well as “optimal care of customers”. Even if these targets may be exemplary in terms of definition and quantification, most of them can not be defined as “health goals” in an actual sense. The majority of targets relates to internal processes and structures, only very few, like for instance those on disease management projects for diabetes have a direct connection with the health status of the population. Some of the targets are exhibited in a table in Appendix 23. Further considerations In the process of setting national-, regional- and other targets, international goals such as the WHO Health for All goals should be also taken into consideration and mapped with the Austrian goals on the lower levels. An example for such a mapping exercise is the outcome of the project “Metamodel Quality” in which a relationship was established between the quality targets of social insurance and the WHO Health for All targets. In the realm of this project a model based on the WHO Health 21 – Health for all in the 21st century goals (released in 1998) was set up and a matching exercise performed between the quality related projects in social insurance and the Health for All targets. A matrix was chosen as display instrument and followed up by an assessment. The project report comes up with 21 recommendations for actions. More information related to this project can be found in Appendix 10. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 254 9. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS Measuring performance of health systems has gained attention in recent years, as marked by an increase in international and national efforts to compare health system performance across countries. Many attempts at performance measurement have been based on a composite indicator generated according to a set of two or three criteria which are typically related to health status without reference to the other functions of the health system. While these exercises provide general impressions of the state of health care in one country compared to another, and may allow countries to be ranked on the basis of the chosen criteria, they fail to identify the specific areas where shortcomings exist and the means by which improvements can be made. Therefore, it is more useful to undertake analyses of health systems from the perspective of the multiple functions of the system including financing, payment methods, resource allocation, access to care, quality of care and satisfaction, and its overarching objective – health improvement. Financing health care Analyses of health systems generally begin with a discussion of financing, which includes overall level of spending and rates of growth, sources of financing, and implications in terms of progressivity or regressivity. Overall, health spending has increased consistently in the past decades across Europe and other developed countries. While previous estimates of health expenditure in Austria have placed it about average among European countries, more recent estimates using the OECD system of health accounts places it much higher: the share of the GDP spent on health care in Austria amounted to 9.6% in 2004 compared to 7.5% based on the former calculation method. This value places Austria above the EU 25 average of 8.6% with only Germany and France showing higher health care spending within Europe. Spending on health care continues to rise in all countries; average annual growth rate from 1992-2002 in Austria was slightly lower than that of the EU15: 6.3% compared to EU15 average of 6.9%.768 Separating the components of financing into public and private sources, it appears Austria has a relatively larger share of private funding than most other European countries. Indeed, the level of private expenditure increased at an annual rate of over 4% from 1997 to 2002, mostly because of increasing user charges. In 2004 Austria had the 3rd highest proportion of private funding in the EU15 and the 9th highest among 30 OECD countries. Within this private component, private health insurance makes up about a quarter, with the remainder derived from out-of-pocket payments. Private insurance in Austria only amounts to 2.4% of total health care expenditure. It is mainly used to pay for better accommodation in the private ward of hospitals, treatment by a certain doctor and reductions in waiting time. However, private health insurance accounts for 7% of the revenue of public hospitals. The reduction of the proportion of total revenue generated through wages (wage quota) in the past has various implications for social insurance. First, it results in a reduction in social insurance contributions. Moreover, revenue generated by social insurance contributions in the branch of health insurance rose between 1993 and 2000 by 26% whilst expenditures in this area increased by 32.3%. Wages depicted a relatively smaller increase than the GDP; the growth rate of expenditures of social health insurance is higher than the GDP growth. In such a situation (the erosion of the contribution base of social insurance) it is important for social insurance to create new options for acquiring funds, such as including income generated through assets in the contribution base. Moreover, inequality in wage income has increased during the past three decades. With respect to gender specific differences in income, the women’s median income is situated at 67.2% of the of men’s median income. Unfortunately comparative analyses of progressivity (the extent to which individuals on higher income are contributing relatively more to the financing of the system) have excluded Austria. However, one can infer on the basis of our analysis of the financing system that Austria would rank relatively low on the scale of progressivity. This results partly from the significant private component to financing, of which two-thirds consists of the most regressive form of funding – out-of-pocket payments, and the other third consists of private health insurance which is largely available to higher income earners and civil servants. Although user charges constitute a significant portion of health spending in Austria, a range of exemptions apply limiting their regressivity. Moreover, since social health insurance, or payroll taxes, are less progressive 768 This growth rate estimate was based on the previous method of expenditure calculation. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 255 than the most common funding alternative – general taxation – the level of progressivity in the Austrian system is lowered. Examining the components of health care financing in Austria more closely, it appears that taxation on income is progressive up to a certain income limit, above this it is regressive, while consumption taxes (e.g. value added tax), which represent the largest share of tax income, have a regressive effect. The share of taxes exercising a progressive effect (income tax, revenue tax, tax on assets) is relatively low. Social insurance contributions are calculated based on the insured’s ability to pay. The burden of insurance contributions of income increases proportionally until a defined earnings limit for chargeable contributions is reached. Beyond this limit contributions are regressive. Social insurance resource redistribution takes place, between high- and low income earners, between generations, between the healthy and the sick and between insured without and with dependants. Access to health care Not only is the performance of the health system measured by the fairness and efficiency of financing, but also by the extent to which access to services is fair, or equitable. Equitable access to health services, i.e. access based on need and not ability to pay, is an oft-pursued goal among European governments. The following barriers are applicable to preventive health services and also to health care services in general: disability (inadequate disabled access to facilities and knowledge of the needs of disabled, discrimination, difficulties in communication (Braille, sign language)), migration (language, entitlement to benefits), and lack of health insurance. Reasons for not accessing health services may be unemployment (less investment in own health), multiple burdens (caring for family members, single parent families) often combined with risk of poverty and lack of knowledge. This report presents the results of two comprehensive analyses of equity in health care use among a selection of European countries. The first uses European Community Household Panel Survey data and analyses equity in the probability of a health care visit and the mean number of annual visits. While GP services are largely equitable or pro-poor, for specialist care, individuals on higher income are more likely to access services after controlling for need (therefore there is pro-rich inequity) in all countries, especially Portugal, Ireland, Italy and Spain. Among the 12 countries included in an analysis of equity in inpatient care particularly significant pro-rich inequity is seen in the probability of an inpatient admission in Portugal, Greece, Italy, Austria, Ireland and Germany. The second study uses data from the Survey of Healthy Ageing and Retirement in Europe to analyse equity in health care utilization among the over-50 population in ten European countries. For GP services, the only countries with pro-rich inequity are Italy, Sweden and Switzerland; however specialist care is pro-rich in Spain, Austria, Sweden, Germany, France, Italy, Switzerland and Denmark. Inpatient care only appears inequitable favouring higher income groups in Greece. In terms of equity in health care utilization, Austria fares quite well. In both comprehensive studies, despite having pro-rich inequity in specialist care, it appears lower than most other countries, and there is no inequity in GP services. However, in the first study, pro-rich inequity in inpatient care in Austria is quite high – indeed Austria is ranked third highest out of 12 European countries. However, this finding is complicated by the fact that it only measures the probability of a hospital admission, and not the number of separate admissions. The causes of inequity appear to largely be income and education. In principle people in Austria receive equal treatment, independent of their income (especially emergency care). There are few indications that services of social insurance in Austria are more easily accessible and consumed more frequently by individuals with a higher income (e.g. visits to specialists). As far as emergency care is concerned treatment is thought to be independent of income, although for elective care waiting times may be shorter for individuals covered by private health insurance. An analysis performed by the regional sickness fund in Carinthia in 2002 showed that patients of the lowest income group incur double the expenses for the fund as patients of the highest income group. High users (the group of insured responsible for 50% of the expenses of the regional fund) mostly belong to the group of the low income earners (€0-900). Cost-sharing arrangements may contribute to inequitable access to care. In Austria some health insurance funds impose user charges for physician visits (flat rate (farmers) co-payments (self-employed, civil LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 256 servants), insured according to the ASVG law pay a yearly charge of €10 for the e-card. Other countries such as France, Italy, Sweden and Switzerland, also impose user charges for physician visits. Austria also has a flat co-payment for prescription drugs and an inpatient co-payment per day up to a 28 day maximum. While exemption mechanisms are in place to protect the most vulnerable groups, such as low income earners and older people on pensions, it is still possible that user charges may deter individuals from seeking care. Further exacerbating potential inequalities resulting from cost sharing, in Austria since insurance funds are authorised to implement fund-specific co-payments, these levels differ across insurance funds. The financial burden of user charges placed on an individual varies according to the affiliation to a certain sickness fund. A couple of studies have calculated average user charges of each group; comparison is difficult though because different definitions of user charges and varying reference bases are used (insured with or without dependents). With respect to income, women of the lowest educational group spent roughly twice as much as women of the highest education group. For men the difference amounts to about a fifth. A study performed by the regional sickness fund in Carinthia shows that insured in lower income groups pay higher average user charges than those in the higher income groups. User charges increase with the age of the insured. Moreover, costs per prescription range between €17.48 (insurance fund of farmers) and € 24.20 (Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business) in 2005. However, in a study commissioned by the WHO only 4.7% of the individuals questioned in Austria stated that they could not afford a certain treatment during the past year. In general it is assumed that user charges in Austria do not, due to extensive exemptions, restrict access to health care in a significant way.769 This is consistent with the analysis of SHARE showing less than <3% of the sample declared to forego care because of costs (among 50+ population), low in comparison to other European countries.770 It is also important to consider specific population groups that may be experiencing significant barriers to accessing health care such as migrants, asylum seekers and refugees. While European law is attempting to harmonise the conditions for asylum seekers to receive health care, there are still obstacles present in some countries. In Austria, about 4.5% of asylum seekers remain without health care cover. Migrants are more likely to be endangered by poverty (28%) than people who are born in Austria (11%), however access to health services should be equal for both groups. Apart from lack of insurance coverage language or cultural barriers may exist, partially combined with lacking knowledge on benefits entitlement. Foreigners may delay seeking medical advice thus then being at risk of having a more severe and chronic sickness spells/illnesses. Geographical barriers to access may exist such as overall availability of services, distance to health care facilities, and difference in proximity to health services across income groups. Austria has among the highest supply of hospital beds in Europe, next to Germany, Czech Republic, and Lithuania. Despite this high availability, data from a Eurobarometer survey in 2002 show that about 40% of Austrian respondents reported access to a hospital in less than 20 minutes, compared to 60% in Belgium, 65% in Italy, and 70% in the Netherlands. Perceived access to GPs is, predictably, much better, with almost 80% of Austrians reporting access within 20 minutes (same as the EU average). When examining the difference in proximity across income groups, Austria fares very well, with almost the lowest discrepancy in reported distance to a hospital between the lowest and highest income quintile in the EU. The number and distribution of contract physicians is regulated by the Location Plan (Stellenplan) which should grant a fair and efficient provision of care through physicians in primary care. Beyond the Location Plan another instrument that aims to ensure an equal distribution of health care facilities is the Austrian Structural Plan for Health Care (Österreichischer Strukturplan Gesundheit, ÖSG). Geographical access in case of emergency is in general in line with international standards. Access to other types of care may, especially in rural areas, be accompanied by longer travel distances, which are largely considered acceptable (max. 1.5 hours). Reimbursement of travel costs varies among the sickness funds. Another instrument to improve access to care is the analytical tool developed by the Hauptverband called REGIOMED with which benchmarks for the provision and utilization of medical services in the ambulatory setting can be calculated to identify over and underprovision. These are used in negotiations related to the Location Plan. 769 770 “Who pays for your health care” accessed at http://www.gewinn.co.at/kredite/content.php?article=888m on 5.01.06 SHARE data can be accessed at the following website: http://www.share-project.org/ LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 257 In addition, it is important to examine the extent to which accessibility in terms of supply of services and personnel may vary across Austria’s regions. Vienna has the most practicing physicians, GPs, specialists, dentists per capita, while Vorarlberg and Burgenland have the least doctors per capita, and Lower Austria and Upper Austria depict a low number of dentists per capita. Most contract doctors per capita can be found in Vienna, the least in rural areas such as Vorarlberg, Burgenland, Upper Austria and Tyrol. Rehabilitation clinics for inpatient care integrated with social insurance funds are mainly situated in the federal states of Upper Austria, Lower Austria and Styria, and integrated ambulatory clinics in Vienna, Styria, Upper Austria and Lower Austria. Tyrol and Vienna had the highest density of doctors per bed in hospitals in 2005; Salzburg and Carinthia were the federal states with the lowest density. The highest density of nonmedical personnel in hospitals (per 100,000 inhabitants) can be found in Vienna, Styria and Carinthia, the lowest in Burgenland. As far as physiotherapists are concerned Vienna has a significantly higher number per capita than other federal states, most of the midwives per capita are in Vorarlberg and Carinthia. Hospital bed density varied considerably in the federal states in 2005, the highest density being in Carinthia (918.07), Salzburg (909.51) Vienna (812.93) and Styria (875.29, the lowest in Vorarlberg (600.12) and Burgenland (565.2)). The highest number of homes for elderly people is in Styria, Upper Austria and Lower Austria, most CTs and MRIs are located in Vienna. Other evidence of equity in the use of services in Austria suggests that socioeconomic factors are impacting utilization patterns, and there are regional inequalities in utilization within the country. Based on 1999 micro census data, participation in health-check ups increased for individuals with a higher level of education. Visits to GPs and ambulatory clinics decreased for individuals with a higher education, while visits to specialists and dentists increased. Participation in health check ups was highest in Vorarlberg (22.9%), followed by Tyrol (20.9%) and Carinthia (17.2%), it was lowest in Lower Austria (4.9%), Vienna (8.7%) and Upper Austria (9.2%).Visits to GPs are most frequent in Lower Austria, Upper Austria and Styria, visits to ambulatory clinics in Vienna. Citizens in Lower Austria, Vienna, and Carinthia consult dentists most often, citizens in Burgenland and Upper Austria least often. Average length of stay per citizen was lowest in Tyrol (5.17 days) and highest in Lower Austria (9.64), the Austrian average being 6.58 days per inhabitant. In 2004 prescriptions per insured (13.8) as well as costs per insured (€ 281.13) were lowest for insured of Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business and highest for insured of the insurance fund of the Austrian Mining Industry (27.9 and €569.69 respectively). Average days spent in hospital in 2005 were between 6.8 days (insurance fund for the self employed) and 7.9 days (occupational sickness funds, sickness fund for the Austrian Mining Industry). The fewest billed cases per contract physician (all medical specialities) were provided in 2005 in Vorarlberg (4,141), the most in Upper Austria (4,664). The tariff reimbursed per case varied between €41.41 in Upper Austria and €51.77 in Lower Austria. The tariff per physician was highest in Lower Austria €219.14 (in 1,000 Euros) and lowest in Carinthia (€193.54). Regulating health care Regulation involves many functions and takes place at many levels of the health system. There are three principle models of organizational relationship between purchasers and providers: (1) integrated; (2) contract; and (3) direct payment to providers. Government may play a regulatory role at national, regional and district levels; many countries have independent monitoring agencies (e.g. UK). Also regulatory functions may be the responsibility of at non-governmental independent or arms-length bodies. There is a general continuum of state authority and supervision that ranges from: command-and-control (e.g. NHS trusts in the UK; public hospitals in Austria and Germany), to arms-length approaches such as private notfor-profit entities with statutory responsibilities (e.g. sickness funds) and private-for-profit companies with or without service agreements with public payers (e.g. private hospitals in Italy and Portugal). In almost all EU countries, health technology assessment (HTA) programs have been established (e.g. through the Federation of Austrian Social Insurance Institution/Drug Evaluation Committee) with the aim to aid national or regional priority setting and health policy processes. As seen in the rest of Europe, HTA is increasingly being used for decision-making; however, further elaboration of HTA activities should be encouraged. Governments are beginning to acknowledge the importance of collecting and reporting data on quality and other performance indicators in an attempt to better regulate the system and improve performance. Austria could take the lead from other countries, such as Germany with the new national quality benchmarking projects, and Demark with the widespread collection of quality indicators, to better inform regulators and LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 258 decision-makers about areas of strength and weakness in the system, and inform patients who could also stimulate quality improvements. Health care provision in Austria is conducted by (1) integrated providers (institutions owned by social insurance funds), (2) by health care providers who have signed a contract with social health insurance, and (3) by private health care providers. The latter may also be accessed by insured persons, whereby they have the option of claiming a refund from their sickness fund afterwards. For the provision of hospital services to the insured population social insurance pays a lump sum based on the so called agreement pursuant to article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act, signed by the Federation and the federal states. The Austrian health system does not have an independent supervisory commission that is comparable to the Audit Commission in the UK. The Austrian system is hierarchical whereby duties and responsibilities are primarily defined by law. It is mainly organized in a federal way, not only in the area of social insurance funds but also in hospital care. Depending on the region the sanitary agencies of the federal states may have a range of duties and responsibilities, primarily in the area of hospital care but formally also in the area of ambulatory care (physicians in surgeries). One serious challenge in Austria is the fragmentation of responsibilities for funding and providing services, especially for secondary care. Although regulation is strongly based on federal (and some state) legislation (in the SHI system, the Federation defines rules and insurance funds implement them and purchase services), regulatory functions are largely decentralized. Thus, Government relies heavily on delegation of regulatory functions and devolution to federal states, for example in the case of hospital care. The Austrian Constitution stipulates that central responsibility for the health care system lies, apart from a few exceptions, with the Federation. Government delegates most of these tasks to the federal states by indirect federal administration arrangements (e.g. hospital care) or to social insurance by way of self governance (e.g. provision of physician care). Recently a new independent institute for research and planning has come into existence, the Health Care Austria Plc (Gesundheit Österreich GmbH). It merges the Healthy Austria Fund (Fonds Gesundes Österreich), the Austrian federal institute for health care (Österreichisches Bundesinstitute im Gesundheitswesen, ÖBIG) and will also include the Austrian federal institute for quality in health care (Österreichisches Bundesinstitut für Qualität im Gesundheitswesen, BIQG). The new institute will be responsible for providing the basis for decision-making for structural planning in health care provision as well as for developing guidelines for quality assurance and health care promotion. Regulation and collection of taxes is primarily performed by the Federation; the revenue is distributed among the Federation, the nine federal states and the communities according to the Financial Equalization Act. A significant legal foundation for the system of funding, particularly for inpatient care, pertaining an important co-ordinating function is the agreement reached between the Federation and the federal states pursuant to article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act. Funding within Social insurance is equally regulated by law, namely in the General Social Insurance Act (ASVG) and in the relevant Social Insurance Acts for the other professions (Self Employed, Civil servants, Farmers, etc.). The Austrian Social insurance system is a pay-as-you-go system. The Federation renders a contingent liability (Ausfallshaftung) in pension insurance, provided that the contributions of the insured do not cover all the expenses. With the self-employed, Federation substitutes the employer and pays the difference between the own contribution and the total sum. Physician services are mainly funded by social health insurance, partially also by private households (non-contract doctors). The areas of prevention and health promotion are financed by social insurance contributions and by tax payments. Social welfare payments are covered mainly by the federal states and the communities, long term care services by the Federation and the federal states. Risk adjustment in Austrian social insurance does not assume a major importance although various instruments for financial equalization are adopted. The intention of these systems is to promote coordination between the funds as well as equalization. The Hauptverband is in charge of equalizing and distributing financial resources. The equalization fund of the regional sickness funds should, according to § 447a ASVG guarantee an equal financial performance i.e. liquidity of the regional sickness funds, and render payments to the funds in accordance with the available financial resources and the legal definitions. Initially the equalization fund included all sickness funds until this was declared unconstitutional (Now only LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 259 the regional funds are part of the fund). In 2005 a restructuring of the equalization fund was agreed upon which aimed at formulating a scientific model for the structural equalization between the regional sickness funds. Now equalization is based on the revenue generated by contributions and by the prescription charge. The average cost for each insured (by age and sex) as well as for insured generating extraordinarily high costs is regarded. In addition to these aspects certain supply related factors such as regional burdens are taken into consideration. Another risk pooling instrument is the equalization fund for hospital financing whereby the sickness funds pay a lump sum for hospital services to the health care agencies established in the federal states (Landesgesundheitsfonds). Allocative efficiency Measures of allocative efficiency, although difficult to estimate, provide an indication of the extent to which the amounts and types of health services are efficient and maximising health gain. One indicator of allocative efficiency is the level of expenditure by health sector. Next to Italy, Austria has the highest level of spending directed to inpatient care (42% of the health care budget) among 14 European countries with available data. This may be indicative of inefficiency since inpatient care is among the most expensive and may reflect deficiencies in the lower levels of the system – primary care and prevention. Indeed, if spending levels are commensurate with the quality of care, spending on public health and prevention represents only 2% of total health spending, less than half the level of many other countries including Finland, Germany, and the Netherlands. One can examine the allocation of health spending across the different sectors, but also the method of allocating funds to the purchasers – typically from governments to health authorities or sickness funds. There has been a trend in Europe gradually moving away from full retrospective reimbursement towards fixed fee schedules, fixed budgets, and activity-based payments. Capitation payments with risk adjustment are becoming an increasingly common method of allocating resources. Risk adjustment seeks to improve equity in resource allocation, based on the premise that individuals’ health care needs vary according to personal, social and geographical characteristics. While most countries make use of a capitation system with risk adjustment, only Austria, Greece and Ireland do not. Funding responsibilities in the Austrian Health care system are fragmented, especially in the area of hospital care, in which the Federation and the federal states as well as social insurance funds and communities occupy an important role. Financial resources of social insurance are raised and used in a decentralized way. 77% of the funds are generated by contributions of the insured, 16% by contributions of the Federation and 8% by other income. Funding of hospital care is partially organized by budgets. Use of financial resources of health insurance funds is, apart from inpatient care, handled autonomously by the individual sickness funds and is based on the obligation to provide services stated in the social insurance laws. The amount of financial resources used for health care is decided by the different funding institutions, social insurance funds, central government, the nine federal states and the communities. In Austria geographical differences in per capita health expenditures exist, however data or research on the topic is very limited. It is possible to link the cost for services to the place of residence of the insured by using the service information system of social insurance (Leistungsinformationssystem, LIVE). Results of comparative analysis should however be treated with great caution. Great variations between the sickness funds in terms of expenditure per insured/beneficiary do exist. In the course of the calculation of health expenditure based on the system of health accounts, it is planned in future to calculate expenditures not only on a national but also on a regional level. Technical efficiency Although it is incredibly difficult to measure efficiency in a complex sector like health, it is widely agreed that improvements in technical efficiency in the health systems of Europe and around the world, are needed. Comparative analyses of technical efficiency on an aggregate level – for example, by measuring health attainment according to the level of health resources and social environment – have attempted to identify high and low performing health systems. Among the higher performing systems include France, Greece, Ireland, Norway, Spain and the UK; and among the lower performing systems include Austria, Belgium, Germany, the Netherlands and Switzerland. Like general measures of performance, there is little value in LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 260 these broad-brush comparisons. Rather, analyses of the functions of the health system that impact technical efficiency are more revealing. Administrative costs in a health system can reveal inefficiency, since these are resources that are not directly involved in health improvement. Comparing 14 countries’ administrative costs shows that some countries are doing better in keeping costs down – in particular the systems funded by taxation – than others. Austria however is performing quite well, by spending 3.6% of total health expenditure on health administration compared to almost 6% in Germany and over 4% in the Netherlands. This slightly lower level of inefficiency in terms of administration is likely attributed to the lack of choice of insurance fund and corresponding risk adjustment mechanisms in Austria unlike Germany and the Netherlands. Supply of resources may be appropriate or inefficient, depending on the mix of services, skills and highand low-cost options. Austria appears to have a relatively high supply of high technology diagnostic devices such as CT and MRI scanners per capita compared to other countries. While this extra capacity may prevent access problems such as waiting times, they may not be used efficiently. Regarding human resources, Austria has a level of physicians that is at about the EU average, but a lower than average number of nurses per capita; therefore there is relatively little opportunity for skill substitution. The efficiency of the hospital sector is often identified in terms of activity statistics such as occupancy rates and average length of stay. Across Europe, the average length of stay in hospital has declined significantly. Current levels suggest Austria is on the low end of the scale, with average length of inpatient stay at around 7 days compared to about 14 in France, and over 10 in Germany. However the number of hospital beds in Austria (especially acute beds) is above the average of the EU countries. Over the past twenty years efforts have been undertaken to reduce beds. Hospital beds per 100,000 inhabitants declined from 9.89 in 1991 to 7.73 in 2004. The number of acute beds has experienced a significant decline in Austria during the past 15 years but is still situated far above the European average. Much of the indicators of technical efficiency depend on the payment methods for health care providers including physicians and hospitals. It is generally argued that among physician remuneration methods, feefor-service promotes increased activity and hence efficiency, while salary and capitation encourages reduced activity and increased referrals, but lowers overall costs. Most health systems rely on a mix of the three general remuneration options. Fee-for-service is the most prevalent payment method in some countries, such as Austria, Belgium, France and Germany. Some countries have been experimenting with introducing more specific incentives into the remuneration scheme, such as payment that is linked to a set of quality indicators as in the UK. Hospital payment methods tend to be based to some extent on performance, in the form of a mix of DRGs and/or fixed budgets for example. Physicians in hospitals are paid by a salary which they receive from the hospital carrier. They are allowed to undertake additional parttime jobs, e.g. to open their own private practice. The payment of a salary could limit productivity in hospital, the scope of activities undertaken outside of the hospital might have an effect on performance in the hospital, and private payments may influence the behaviour of doctors. Payment of other health care personnel can also impact efficiency. For instance, with pharmacists in Austria paid on a margin rather than a flat payment, there is no incentive for pharmacists to dispense cheaper drugs, therefore improve efficiency. The way health care providers are paid for their efforts can strongly influence their behaviour. In Austria, physicians who signed a contract with social health insurance are usually paid by a blended system, which is based on fee-for service payment and supplemented by a capitated payment (per patient, for a certain time span). The level of the capitated payment varies amongst the sickness funds and may also depend on the specialty of the doctor. Special insurance funds (Sonderversicherungsträger), SVA, BVA and VAEB pay their contract partners (physicians) by fee-for service payment only, some sickness funds have a very low basic reimbursement (Carinthia, Lower Austria). This type of reimbursement would lead to the assumption that physicians are incentivised to maximise the number of services they provide. In order to counteract this, health insurance funds implement steering mechanisms in their reimbursement catalogues and/or general contracts, for instance billing restrictions, capping of benefits provided and degressive payments (price-volume trade-off once a certain volume of benefits is reached). Reimbursement for preventive services is not linked to the fulfilment of defined targets, such as reaching a certain number of people. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 261 Social insurance pays a lump sum for public hospitals according to § 447 para.1 ASVG. The lump sum covers all services in the areas of inpatient care, part-inpatient care, day-clinical and outpatient care. On January 1 in 1997 a performance orientated reimbursement system for hospitals, Leistungsorientierte Krankenanstaltenfinanzierung, LKF, was introduced, substituting the existing reimbursement based on undifferentiated daily payments. About half of costs are based on performance orientated funding and on countrywide standardized point values per diagnosis related group (LKF core area). This system is complemented by lump sum budgets. It entails the incentive of increasing the amount of services provided (maximising points), of admitting certain ambulatory patients to inpatient wards or of engaging in DRG creep. A partial lack in depth of the case groups (considering the severity of the disease) exists and it is not always possible to distinguish between acute and chronic. There are no incentives for the provision of preventive services. Moreover there is duplication of services and no integration of primary and secondary care may lead to fragmented care. The LKF system has increased transparency in inpatient care; implicit standards are defined and a relationship between diagnosis and services is established. The introduction was followed by a decrease of the average length of stay in hospitals. However the number of inpatient-admissions has gone up constantly, driven partly by the increase in day-clinic cases (which are categorised as inpatient). Increases in costs were contained by capping expenditures. Studies state that the reduction in the increase in costs only had a short term effect and that the LKF System has led to the practice of upcoding. Other indicators of efficiency include the extent to which substitution policies are in place and continuity of care is encouraged. Substitution can take place between prescription drugs and also health care personnel. Generic prescribing in Austria is not encouraged, furthermore, generic substitution by the pharmacist is not allowed. Health insurance funds undertake a range of efforts to increase the share of generics (generic products) prescribed, partially employing financial incentives to motivate physicians. With respect to substitution of personnel in the health care sector a tendency of patients to directly consult a medical specialist instead of a GP has been observed. Areas of responsibility of physicians partially shift to other health professionals; duties of GPs will be extended (e.g. administration and monitoring of disease management programs). A couple of studies have compared the cost of providing treatment inside or outside of the hospital largely finding lower costs in the latter. Hofmarcher et al.771 concluded that a potential for substitution between outpatient departments in hospitals and practices of medical specialists does exist, however the scope of this potential is not clear. Furthermore they urge that a simple comparison of average costs is not valid and that the aims of service provision of each provider have to be taken into consideration. Health care delivery is one of the key functions of the health system, and can be organized in a multitude of ways that each impact performance. The extent to which there is continuity of care is of utmost importance and greatly influences the efficiency and effectiveness of the system. Continuity of care consists of both care of an individual (across illnesses, services, etc) and care over time. Better continuity of care can lead to improved efficiency through shorter consultation times, more effective clinical decisions, and fewer errors and duplications. Continuity of care is an essential part of health systems in light of the ageing population, increasing prevalence of complex chronic diseases and co-morbidities, and the aim to improve efficiency. The Austrian health system is characterised by a large number of actors, who are involved in funding and/or providing health care services, the most important being social insurance, the federal states, the federation, the local governments and private providers. Due to this fragmentation there is a considerable lack of continuity of care at all levels of the Austrian health care system as well as a lack of communication between the different levels. Continuity of care and co-operation between ambulatory providers (physicians, other health care professionals) hardly takes place, though the introduction of the e-card (increased use of information technology incl. computers) and the future introduction of the electronic health record may encourage and facilitate communication between providers. Continuity of care between ambulatory and secondary care is hampered once again due to fragmentation of funding and responsibility. Social insurance pays for a great share of inpatient care but does hardly have any say in service provision. Continuity of care 771 Hofmarcher, M., Riedel, M., Röhrling, G. (2001).″ Focus: Doctor's Practice or Outpatient Department: One case is not one case.". Health System Watch IV, supplement of the Austrian journal of social insurance Soziale Sicherheit, pp. 11-23. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 262 following discharge of hospital, especially for patients who require more extensive care such as chronically ill patients is subject to considerable regional variations, no standardized procedures exist. Health care provision in long-term care and for social services is fragmented. It is difficult to compare providers and services vary across the regions. Also the provision of other services in health care, such as emergency services involves multiple actors making co-ordination extremely complicated. Instruments encouraging integrated care are for instance planning instruments such as the Structural Plan for Health Care (Österreichischer Strukturplan Gesundheit) or the Location Plan. Mechanisms to promote coordination and prevent shifting of resources are the agreement according to article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act, the co-ordination mechanism and sanctioning mechanism and the recently introduced Reformpool. A range of projects to promote integrated care exist on various levels. In social insurance the regional sickness fund of Vienna has recently become the competence centre for integrated care. The new e-card was introduced to improve continuity of care and efficiency in the delivery of health services. In the first stage of expansion the e-card only replaces the paper-health insurance voucher and verifies the patient’s entitlement towards the physician in Austria with respect to utilising services of contract physicians in real time. In addition the e-card infrastructure is used to handle the prior authorisation for pharmaceuticals. Insured received their e-cards between May and November 2005 by mail. A yearly service charge of €10.00 is levied by the employer. This results in lower expenses for severely or chronically ill patients as costs are not linked to the amount of times the patient accesses services. Self employed and civil servants do not pay any service charge. In the future the card should fulfil a variety of additional purposes, amongst others it will be used in other areas of care such as inpatient care, for the administration of the e-prescription or the transmission of sensitive data. The e-card infrastructure links all physicians in Austria electronically. A few population groups are not yet included in the e-card scheme but for most of them strategies for future involvement have already been elaborated. Quality of care Another dimension by which to analyse the health system is quality of care. There are a multitude of possible indicators of quality that can be collected, although the difficulty defining and measuring quality has led to a relative paucity of reliable data on an international level. One indicator of quality is patient satisfaction. Satisfaction with health care varies quite a lot across Europe, as revealed through various European-level surveys, and on the whole, Austria comes out on top. During the past years not only the notion of quality but also the awareness that more ought to be done to improve quality has received increasing attention in Austria. Quality is defined in the Quality in Health Care Act (Gesundheitsqualitätsgesetz), in § 2 para.2 as “Degree of fulfilment of the attributes of patientorientated, transparent and efficient provision of health care services”. The Quality in Health Care Act came into effect on January 1 2005 and represents an embracing of all hitherto existing quality regulations which are distributed across a range of laws. Provisions not only apply over the whole of Austria but span all professions and sectors (coverage of all actors in the health system). In the course of the negotiations related to the agreement according to the article 15a of the Federal Constitutional Act on the restructuring of the health care system and hospital funding, valid through 20012004, the Structural Commission (Strukturkommission) was given the responsibility of initiating a country wide system of quality reporting. For the first time it was debated to establish a database for quality projects as well as a database for quality related strategies in hospitals. Both were realised in the form of pilot projects. The results and the final report on quality reporting and the pilot projects were handed over to the ministry but have, to date, not been published. Other institutions such as the Austrian Social Insurance for Occupational risks and the Vienna Hospitals Association publish quality reports. In Social insurance the topic of quality has received increasing attention, which is visible in the targets in the Balanced Scorecard but also in the rising number of projects in this area. The sickness funds perform numerous projects looking at topics such as developing guidelines for certain indications, defining standards for care, improving the quality of PAP smears, increasing the share of generics and improving prescribing behaviour. Measures for quality control in integrated health care institutions exists as well as for contract partners. Controls of contract partners are usually ex-post controls to check compliance with quality provisions in the tariff catalogue as well as reactions to patient complaints. A considerable problem LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 263 is the fact that social insurance only disposes of few possibilities to actually measure the quality of the services provided, another that it does not have appropriate instruments to sanction, only in the case of fraud, severe treatment errors or the suspicion of abuse. Quality targets of the sickness funds are usually related to the provision of services and included in the general contract or the tariff catalogues. In the area of inpatient care quality standards of the Austrian Structural Plan for health are mandatory. The 1993 amendment to the Hospital Act dictated the establishment of commissions for quality assurance in hospitals. Quality control in ambulatory care takes place by means of voluntary (certification, accreditation, quality circles, peer reviews, guidelines and recommendations) as well as, mandatory measures introduced with the fifth amendment of the Physician Act. It is organised as a self-assessment. By 2008 about 15,000 practices will be evaluated, which are then re-assessed every two to three years. Evaluations started midApril 2006. The responsibility for the quality assessment, according to § 118a Physician Act, lies with the Quality assurance association ÖQMed which was founded especially for this reason and is owned to 100% by the Physicians. On a national level Austria does not have an own agency or institution to ensure patient safety. Some projects promoting patient safety were initiated. In the course of the Quality in Health Care Act directives related to patient safety may be enacted in the near future, the new Federal Institute for Quality in Health Care (now part of the Health Care Austria Plc.) will most likely be responsible for patient safety in some way or the other. In case of damages resulting from medical treatment or omission, two avenues of approach may be chosen: judicial and extrajudicial. Patients may appeal to civil courts or, in the course of an extrajudicial settlement, to patient lawyers who aim at obtaining a compensation payment by appealing to the liability insurance either of the health care institution or of the doctor who provided treatment. Responsibility of court depends on the origin of the matter in question (penal law or civil law). Medical errors represent a significant cost and health burden in Europe; surveys reveal patients in some countries are more concerned with medical errors (e.g. in Greece, Poland, the UK, Slovenia) than others (e.g. Austria and Sweden); and are more confident in their doctors in some countries (e.g. Austria and France). So far Austria has not developed a national concept for reporting medical errors. Some areas in health care have already developed mechanisms or set up structures (reporting of adverse effects of medicines, introduction of a heamovigilance register). A couple of initiatives have been started i.e. are encouraged by the Ministry, the Hauptverband and the ÖGAM (Austrian Association of General Practitioners). For instance, more hospitals are using error reporting systems. Until now the legal and structural framework for error reporting has been missing, equally the awareness for the importance of the topic. Patients cannot access data on medical errors nor can they assess medical risks. In the future greater transparency should be ensured by means of quality reporting. Patient choice Patient choice of insurance, provider, and treatment options exist to varying degrees in Europe. While some argue that patient choice has intrinsic value, others suggest that in some contexts patient choice can stimulate competition between providers which can lead to improvements in quality and efficiency of care. European surveys reveal that levels of patient choice of provider in Austria are among the highest in Europe. Although this high level of choice is valued by the population, one may question the extent to which this current level compromises continuity of care. In Austria social insurance is governed by law and is based on the principle of compulsory insurance. Affiliation to one of the 20 social health insurance funds of an insured person is based on their employment (type, place) and in a few cases by his place of residence (e.g. for pensioners) more or less eliminating the chances of risk selection. Dependants are covered, as well as pensioners, unemployed, low-income earners or students. Foreigners, tourists and asylum seekers are covered under certain circumstances. At the end of June 2003 up to 205 000 people from the age of 15 years or 3.1% of the resident population from age 15 years are not covered by national health insurance. Options are very limited in the Austrian social insurance system, a change to an alternative fund occurs only in a few cases. Those insured with the Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business have the most options available. Voluntary insured persons also have choice of sickness fund. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 264 The Austrian social insurance allows the insured person free choice of which doctor they visit. They can visit doctors having a contract with social insurance, doctors in contract group practices, doctors in facilities provided by health insurance funds (clinics), doctors in contract establishments (e.g. hospital outpatient departments) or private doctors (who do not have a contract with a sickness fund), doctors in private group practices, or doctors in private facilities across the whole of Austria. The number of physicians (specialists) accessed within a defined time period (e.g. per quarter) may be limited; regulations at the sickness funds vary. It must be taken into consideration, that the freedom of choice can be exercised more readily in more highly populated areas than in rural areas primarily because the concentration of health care provided is higher. Basically the person insured with social health insurance is permitted to personally select the hospital at which he is to receive in-patient treatment. Restrictions may arise because of reimbursement of transportation costs to the hospital. Due to the system of statutory social insurance risk selection is very restricted, resulting in a more equitable health care system. Some insured of Austrian Social Insurance Authority for Business (§ 5 GSVG) as well as voluntary insured persons have some options of choice of insurance (i.e. the possibility to opt out of mandatory social insurance). The first group includes professionals who tend to have a higher income and lower risk, who, by opting out of the statutory system may reduce the overall level of revenue for the system. Persons choosing to take out voluntary insurance are people who are not affected by any provisions of statutory insurance and who are not covered as dependants. Service coverage of the legal health insurance is comprehensively regulated in the social insurance laws (ASVG, B-KUVG, GSVG, BSVG and FSVG). Health insurance funds retain only limited scope to deliver additional voluntary services (regulated in their statutes). With respect to decisions on including new services in the benefits package no standardized procedure exists for all sickness funds. Evidence based medicine, HTA and health economic evaluations are only slowly gaining ground in Austria. However negotiations and policy making is still highly influential when deciding on benefits or tariffs. However, differences in the spectrum of services provided by different insurance funds can occur due to various reasons, such as legal variations, differing contractual provisions, variations in the statutes of the funds, in their financial situation, differing levels of co-payments or the branch of the fund (health care-, accident-, pension insurance). Health improvement The ultimate goal of the health system is to improve the health status of individuals, leading to aggregate improvements on a population level. Improvements have been seen across Europe in terms of crude measures of population health such as life expectancy at birth and at age 65. Although health status has improved in all EU-15 Member States since the 1970s, significant inequalities remain between and within countries. In terms of the new Member States in which the political and economic transition significantly worsened health, some have experienced noticeable improvements in recent years and in some cases approach or surpass the EU average in health attainment. Austrians’ life expectancy is above EU average and appears to be increasing. Taking the EU 15 ranking Austrian female life expectancy has changed over time from 11th (1980) to 7th (2003) and Austrian male life expectancy from 14th (1980) to 9th (2003). Based on the OECD data female life expectancy was ranked 19th in 1980 and 10th in 2003 out of 30 countries. Male life expectancy in Austria was ranked 22nd in 1980 and has increased to hold the 15th rank in 2003. Austria is one of the European countries with the lowest infant mortality; maternal mortality is significantly lower than the EU-average. In terms of avoidable mortality, evidence suggests there has been better progress in treatable than preventable diseases in Austria. This may reflect the curative focus of health care in Austria until recently, which has lately changed to a prioritization of prevention. In Austria, the prevalence of overweight and obesity has increased, in accordance with the international trend. It is on the rise in all age groups, but especially for children and young people. An East-West divide can be observed such that obesity prevalence is higher in the East than the West. In Austria 29% of the adult population (older than 15 years) smokes. Tobacco consumption is increasing among women but falling for Austrian men. Austria holds the first rank in Europe with 4% of the 11 year olds, 15% of the 13 year-olds and 45% of the 14 year-olds. The share of 15 year-olds smoking daily is 20% for boys and 26% for girls which is significantly above the rest of the EU. For women the risk of dying from lung cancer has risen LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 265 dramatically over the last 20 years. Alcohol is a serious problem. Approximately 5% of the adult population can be considered chronically addicted to alcohol. Moreover, the rate of deaths due to cirrhosis of the liver is the highest in Europe. Inequalities in health are evident in Austria. The risk of poverty is 11% for persons born in Austria, and 23% for immigrants who have been granted Austrian citizenship. Male and female immigrants run the highest risk of poverty, at 28%. Women are particularly threatened by poverty, single households are generally at a higher risk. In families with 3 or more children and families with small children, there is an increase of poverty, particularly when the woman is not working. 6% of the Austrian population are manifestly poor. In principle poor people do not receive a lower quality of care by the Austrian health system than wealthier people. However, there is a correlation between low income, poorer subjective health and modified utilization of health care. In addition, morbidity, measured in the number of episodes of illness and the duration of the episodes, decreases with a higher level of education. Unemployed report a higher morbidity than employed. An analysis performed by the Hauptverband shows that the per capita cost for physician services, pharmaceuticals and dental care is lower for consumers of services with foreign citizenship of all ages compared to the per capita cost of consumers of services with Austrian citizenship.772 Especially for insured older than 55 years there is a remarkable difference between the two groups. In terms of preventive care, social health insurance offers comprehensive preventive health check ups (youth check ups, 16-18 years, and for adults> 18); a new “evidence based” program started in October 2005. Further prevention-related services are certain vaccinations and genetic examinations. In addition health promotion efforts (for healthy, workers, pregnant, newborn, children), programs to improve dental care as well as health care education. Measures for health promotion offered by social insurance are for instance treatment in spas or in convalescent homes. Other initiatives include examinations of school children, mother-child examinations and physical examinations of young men before performing the military service. A national mammography screening program will be adapted in the near future (National Programs on molecular genetic analysis for breast cancer and ovarian cancer) although structural requirements have to still be met before introducing it at a national level. However for other disease categories, screening programs are only opportunistic and should be elaborated based on international evidence. Screening programs which have been evaluated include “the 20 year evaluation of national blood pressure education campaigns” (temporary effects of improving blood pressure awareness) the maternity care program “Mother-Child-Passport (may have led to an increase in the mean birth weight) and the “Evaluation of Austrian Newborn Hearing Screening” (greatly increasing the proportion of children whose hearing impairment is diagnosed before six months of age). Furthermore evaluation of PSA screening for prostate cancer for the region of Tyrol (trends in the reduction of prostate cancer mortality differ significantly between Tyrol and the rest of Austria). 9.1 Options for research Research could be done to identify high service users and then assigning them to a personal doctor or clinical team to improve continuity of care. Clinical information could be better shared across areas and levels of care. One could also evaluate continuity of care analysing if patients shop around when accessing care or if they remain with the same health care provider Additional quality indicators and standardized measures of waiting times could be developed and eventually released to the public, in order to increase transparency and empower patients. Alternative models for dealing with the shortage of qualified nursing staff and the lack of standards for care could also be evaluated. Research assessments on the current needs and also projections of future human resources need could be undertaken with the aim of meeting health care needs of the population and ensuring an efficient skill mix. It would also be worthwhile to further evaluate the potential for substituting hospital for community care. 772 Grillitsch (Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger, HVB). 23 June 2006 via email LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 266 Provider payment schemes could be evaluated in terms of impacts on costs and outcomes; possible elaborations to the current schemes may be assessed and considered in terms of creating incentives for quality and productivity improvements. With regards to hospital payments, further research on hospital productivity would be useful, in particular continuing to monitor and evaluate the new activity-based financing scheme in light of the possibility of DRG-creep. Also payment methods for doctors in hospitals could be evaluated in terms of the impact on their behaviour (e.g. fees for private patients, part-time jobs). Data could be collected on possible risk selection of providers based on patient characteristics and the affiliation of a person to a certain sickness fund. More research can be done on the financing system to investigate the level of progressivity. Furthermore, an integrated data base could be created to evaluate trends in income distribution. And further research on redistribution of income could be performed since the current data is fairly old, and unsatisfactory. The risk equalization scheme represents an important step towards ensuring equity in the system though effects might be limited as the equalization fund is restricted to the nine regional sickness funds only and encompasses a comparably small amount of financial funds. However, this scheme should be evaluated, and possibly elaborated to better measure need. With regards to user fees, a study on the willingness of patients to make co-payments when utilising health services could shed light on what is the appropriate level of fees. Further activities in the field of patient safety could be encouraged, and projects performed so far could be evaluated in order to create a legal and structural framework for error reporting (national standards). The e-card should be continually evaluated in terms of the impact on continuity of care, efficiency, and any possible impact of the introduction on the utilization of services (for example, increased access to specialist care). In the field of effectiveness of the health system in Austria there is a need for further evidence that public health programmes and interventions are successful. Evidence is needed that the intervention is effective, but further it must be investigated whether the intervention works in the short term and whether its effects are sustained over longer periods. In addition evidence must be gathered as to whether the programme is suited to the particular epidemiological setting, health system and cultural context. More specifically, the new mammography screening program should be evaluated for effectiveness and cost-effectiveness, and extensions to other disease areas should be considered based on this evaluation and international evidence. The new health check-up program also reflects the increasing importance paid to prevention; however, this should also be subject to monitoring and evaluation. Furthermore, as the health trends indicate emerging and persistent health threats such as alcohol consumption, obesity, and smoking, particularly among young people, more research is needed to develop national surveys focusing on these areas, and to initiate public health programs targeting population groups, such as youths, most at risk.773 The new diabetes management program should be evaluated in terms of health outcome and patient satisfaction. Further programs for other disease areas could also be introduced. Further, in light of the ageing population, initiate research and prevention activities for elderly people living at home alone. Research into avoidable mortality which provides an indication of the quality and overall performance of health care should be updated and perhaps conducted on a regional level, thus highlighting and variation in performance within the country. Data could also be collected on postoperative mortality and re-admissions to hospitals (on an individual basis). Although there is evidence of barriers to access and inequalities in utilization of health services, further research could address regional variations in access to care, costs and health outcomes. More detailed surveys of utilization and socio-economic factors can shed light on the existing inequalities on a more micro-level, for example focussing on specific disease or service areas. Also, activities of the sickness funds to inform and educate their insured population such as the health care information centres established in Salzburg and Burgenland (Gesundheitsinformationszentren, GIZ) could be evaluated. In light of the 773 Reference should be made to: Dür, W., Mravlag, K. (2002). Health and behaviour related to health care of children and adolescents. Results of the 6th HBSC survey 2001 and trends from 1990 to 2001. Series original work, studies, research reports, Federal Ministry of Social Security, Generations and Consumer Protection. Vienna). LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 267 increasing cross-border patient mobility, the care needs of migrants could be investigated with the aim at harmonising the care provided. Research could be commissioned at Austrian level in areas of health economics, health services research and health policy to evaluate the current status to better understand the dynamics of the Austrian health system. A special fund for research could be set up drawing on funds from federal and state government and insurance funds that is at an arms-length from government. This institute could commission work to local institutions such as universities and research centers in order to address the above areas. LSE Project Framework Performance Assessment 268