Textiles and the Historical Emergence of Gender Equality in China*
Transcription
Textiles and the Historical Emergence of Gender Equality in China*
Textiles and the Historical Emergence of Gender Equality in China* Melanie Meng Xue UCLA Anderson School of Management This Version: November 2015 Abstract This paper tests the hypothesis that pre-modern textile production leads to greater gender equality. I exploit variation in pre-modern textiles at the county level to identify their effects on gender equality since 1300. I find despite the the lack of benefits of working outside home, places where women were more productive in textile production developed more favorable views towards working women and witnessed rising gender equality. Pre-modern textile production is negatively correlated with prenatal sex selection, and positively correlated with wife heading the household and with share of women with political and managerial roles. My results are robust to using various subsamples, sex ratios from other cohorts, other gender outcomes, alternative hypotheses, an instrumental variable analysis, and a micro-level analysis. I also investigate the effects of large political and economic shocks after 1850, and find the effects of pre-modern textile production to be overall highly resilient. I document an intermediate effect of textiles on women’s probability of survival upon widowhood dating back to 1500. In addition, I show that women exposed to preindustrial textile production were more likely to participate in the labor force as early as at the onset of China’s industrialization in the 20th century. Using survey data, I show that in contemporary China, individuals in counties with a pre-modern textile history indeed have more progressive gender moderns and weaker son preference. Keywords: Culture, historical persistence, gender norms, son preference, relative productivity JEL Codes:J16 N35 O33 O53 *I would like to thank Sascher Becker, John Brown, Joyce Burnett, Shuji Cao, Latika Chaudhary, Daniel Chen, Bill Collins, Lena Edlund, James Fenske, Philip Hoffman, Paola Giuliano, Remi Jedwab, Saumitra Jha, Noel Johnson, Mark Koyama, Timur Kuran, James Kung, Nan Li, Debin Ma, John Nye, Ömer Ózak, Nancy Qian, Thomas Rawski, Gary Richardson, Eric Schneider, Yan Se, Nico Voigtländer, Bin Wong and audiences at ASREC 2013, CES 2014, “Deep Causes of Economic Development” at Utrecht (2014), EHA 2014, EHS 2014, GMU-AU Economic History Workshop (2012), HKEA (2014), the International Workshop on Economic Analysis of Institutions at Xiamen University (2013), NEUDC(2015), Shanghai University of Economics and Finance (2014), World Congress of Cliometrics Society (2013), WADES (2014), and WEHC (2015). All the remaining errors are the fault of the author. [email protected] I Introduction Gender discrimination is extremely common across the world. Going beyond traditional research on the economic status and political rights of women, recent work has paid increasing attention to the cultural determination of gender attitudes (Fernández, 2007; Fernández and Fogli, 2009; Fortin, 2005; Jayachandran, 2015). In particular, Alesina, Giuliano, and Nunn (2013) and Hansen, Jensen, and Skovsgaard (2015) have focused on the pre-modern roots of gender norms, highlighting historical agriculture in shaping gender roles and gender norms. This paper builds on this strand of literature to investigate pre-modern roots of gender equality. It does so by focusing on textile production—the main economic activity of women in most preindustrial societies. Alesina, Giuliano, and Nunn (2013) explore how traditional agricultural practices influenced the historical gender division of labor and the modern levels of gender equality across countries.1 They find that plough cultivation in pre-industrial periods led to an important belief that the natural place for women is within the home. In contrast to Alesina, Giuliano, and Nunn (2013), this paper explores a setting where women works inside home, but the productivity of women varies. I distinguish between two channels through which pre-modern production could have shaped gender norms and beliefs: working inside or outside home, versus women’s role in providing for family. Pre-modern China offers an ideal testing ground because the predominant ethnic group, Han Chinese, used the plough; however, women’s status varied tremendously within that ethnic group. The plough was operated in the fields, mainly by men; textiles were produced at home, mainly by women. Types and quantities of textiles varied greatly across regions. Women in some places were far more productive than women elsewhere, partly due to more favorable climatic and geographic conditions. I hypothesize that women doing highly productive work to provide for her family, even at home, can increase their status. The extent of variation in women’s status in China provides an ideal setting to study the historical and modern causes of gender inequality. In contemporary China, a leading indicator of gender inequality is sex ratio at birth. Across China a tremendous amount of variation is found in the degree of male bias in this measure. Some counties have maintained close-to-normal sex ratios at birth, whereas in other parts, sex ratio imbalances have become increasingly more severe since sex-selective technology became available in the late 1980s. According to 2000 Chinese Population Census, among all 2876 counties, in Jincheng, 102 boys were born per 100 girls; whereas in Erzhou, 170 boys were born per 100 girls. The amount of male bias in sex ratio at birth is not a simple function of economic development. As Jayachandran (2015) points out, the problem of the male-skewed sex ratio at birth cannot be explained by the process of development: sex ratio imbalances have been intensifying, not lessening, with economic development. Sex ratio at birth more reflects long-standing prejudice against girls. Hence I use sex ratio at birth as a 1 For surveys of field see Guiso et al. (2006); Bisin et al. (2011) and Nunn (2012). 1 main outcome variable to test the impact of pre-modern textiles on gender equality. To identify the causal effect of pre-modern textile production on modern outcomes, including sex ratio at birth, I employ a variety of empirical strategies. First, I collect information on premodern textile production collected from thousands of local gazetteers. I end up with a sample of 1513 counties in my main analysis. Second, I link this data to contemporary measures of gender equality. My outcome variables include sex ratio at birth, women’s education, wife heading the household among married couples, share of women with political roles and managerial roles, gender-role attitudes and son preference. Examining variation across counties and individuals, I find a strong positive relationship between pre-modern textiles and gender equality today. The baseline estimates suggest that pre-modern textile production is associated with a reduction in sex ratio at birth by a quarter of its standard deviation. Pre-modern textiles are negatively correlated with sex ratio imbalances at birth, and positively correlated with wife heading the household among married couples and with share of women with political roles and managerial roles. Pre-modern textiles predict more favorable views about women’s natural ability relative to men. People in areas with pre-modern textiles are more likely to believe that women should be as career-focused as men. To account for historical and modern factors that might also play a role in modern gender outcomes, I include controls for a number of historical characteristics of each county, such as agricultural suitability, proximity to the Grand Canal or the Yangtze River, treaty port status, as well as a set of geographic controls, such as latitude, longitude, ruggedness and distance to coast. I also control for current per capita GDP, share of agricultural workforce, share of non-agricultural household registration, share of ethnic population, and provincial capital. Region and province fixed effects are included in all specifications. In running various robustness checks and considering alternative hypothesis, I also analyze the role of tea production, rice production, level of development prior to cotton textile production, historical postal routes, Christian missionary interventions, present-day textile manufacturing, educational attainment, and migration. My results are robust to an instrumental variable approach. Farnie (1979) points out that relative humidity played a key role in textile production.2 Humidity makes cotton fibers more pliable and reduces the chance of breakages in the yarn. Humidity is positively correlated with the quality of final products until the effect flattens out approximately at 80%. Hardly any cotton textiles can be produced when relative humidity drops below 60%. This motivates the use of county-level relative humidity as an instrument for pre-modern textile production. I aggregate monthly average relative humidity of each county, based on their contribution to a suitable environment for spinning and weaving, into a humidity-for-weaving index. This rationale behind this index is to approximate the number of months available for cotton textile production with 2 Fairbank (1978) discusses the relationship between a relative humid climate of Jiangsu and the greater tensile strength and evenness of yarn. 2 a gradient to quality and efficiency. I obtain IV estimates that are comparable to the OLS estimates providing further confidence that these coefficients can be causally interpreted. To explain the mechanisms through which pre-modern textiles affect modern outcomes, I review the history of widow survival in China, examine a number of outcomes of textile production in the past, and carefully consider the likely effects of several large political and economic shocks on the persistence of gender norms. I first show that pre-modern textiles predict higher survival rates of widows as early as the Ming period, suggesting that textiles were already empowering women historically. I go on to demonstrate female labor participation pattern in the earliest stages of China’s industrialization. I find women in regions with pre-modern textiles were far more likely to be represented in the labor force in the early 20th century. I carefully evaluate the effect of adopting western institutions, the influence of missionary activities, the formation of the Chinese communist state, and recent economic reforms in China. Little evidence is found that any of the large political and economic shocks in modern China have severely confounded the estimates I obtain on pre-modern textiles. Many shocks could have had a level effect on gender norms, but they are rarely correlated with pre-modern textiles. Even when they are correlated, they do not seem to affect my main results. I find the persistence effects pre-modern textiles are overall highly resilient, despite some suggestive evidence that large political or economic shocks could temporarily or even permanently weaken the persistence. Before I conclude, I use Chinese Social General Surveys to provide direct evidence on pre-modern textiles shaping gender-role attitudes and son preference in contemporary China. Previous studies have showed increased women’s earnings lead to female empowerment (Anderson and Eswaran, 2009; Ashraf, Karlan, and Yin, 2010; Deininger, Goyal, and Nagarajan, 2010). In studying the determinants of female autonomy, Anderson and Eswaran (2009) find earned income contributes more to women’s autonomy relative to unearned income, and that only employment outside their husbands’ farms contributes to women’s autonomy. The relationship between sex-specific income and survival of daughters in East Asia has been documented by Qian (2008). Qian interprets the finding that excess female mortality is decreasing in female earnings in terms of women’s increasing bargaining power in the household. My paper shows the shift in women’s relative earnings can change gender norms in the long run. I provide evidence that women enjoyed greater autonomy and higher social status in areas with pre-modern textile production; relative outcomes of women continue to be better even when pre-modern textile production is long out of the picture. I argue that pre-modern textiles shaped cultural beliefs about the women’s capability and their proper role in providing for a family. However, there are also alternative arguments that suggest that part of the long-term impact arises because pre-modern textile production promoted the development of formal institutions, gender-specific economic opportunities and overall wealth that may favor women. To rule out the first channel, I rely on within-country, within-region, and within-province variation, where 3 formal institutions are largely identical and policies are enforced to a similar extent.3 Also, unlike the west, the Chinese state standardized family practices across regions, classes and dialect groups by the late imperial period, with far fewer time and space variation in inheritance practices, marriage rates, naming practices and patrilocality (Ebrey, 1990; Ropp, 1994). After 1949, pervasive reforms in favor of gender equality took place. Formal institutions were created to guarantee female employment. Due to a high degree of centralization in legislation, official labor laws or laws on sex discrimination hardly varied from place to place. All of these create beneficial conditions for me to identify the impact of historical determinants on present-day gender outcomes. To account for the second channel, I control for sectoral composition today, including scale of textile production and agricultural workforce. To best account for the third channel, I control for both current per capita GDP. I show that overall wealth alone hardly explains the large and systematic differences in sex ratio at birth as documented in this paper. This paper contributes to the literature on the historical determinants of cultural norms and beliefs. Many of these document the persistent impact of a negative shock on current cultural values such as Nunn and Wantchekon (2011)’s work on the effects of the trans-Atlantic slave trade on corruption and trust today and Voigtländer and Voth (2012)’s study of the persistence of antisemitic beliefs in Germany. My study is most closely related to those papers that study how economic factors have shaped contemporary gender norms such Grosjean and Khattar (2014) who examine conservative gender norms and its origins in historical marriage market conditions in Australia.4 This paper also contributes to the literature on parental gender bias and sex ratio imbalances by identifying an important source of differentials in sex ratios. Edlund (1999) explicitly models sex ratios in relation to son preference, indicating several factors that contribute to unbalanced sex ratios. Jayachandran (2015) confirms the crucial importance of cultural factors in sex ratio imbalances. Daul and Moretti (2008) finds evidence for parental gender bias in the U.S. that parents favor boys over girls. Others have studied son preference, sex-selective abortions, and changes in sex ratios in non-western countries (Gupta, 2014; Li and Lavely, 2003).5 In particular, Chung and Gupta (2007) suggests income levels play a key role in unbalanced sex ratios and that sex ratios can change in nonlinearity through different stages of development.6 Besides, 3 Despite the highly centralized law making process, policies can be implemented by local governments with greater latitude. 4 Other relevant studies include Jha (2013) who shows that a cities in India that were medieval trading ports experienced significantly less religious riots between Muslims and Hindus in the period after 1850. Grosjean (2011) examines the persistence of a culture of honor among Americans of Scots-Irish descent. She finds that this culture of honor results in higher homicide rates among Scots-Irish in the US South and Mountain West but not elsewhere and argues that this culture has only persisted where formal institutions are comparatively weak. 5 Contrary to the conclusions of the above studies, Oster (2005) finds evidence that that much of sex ratio imbalances in developing countries can be attributed to Hepatitis B. 6 Almond et al. (2013) find positive incomes shocks from land reforms increased sex ratios. Finally, the economic consequences of sex ratio imbalances have also attracted scholarly attention in recent years. Wei and Zhang (2011) links sex ratio imbalances to differential saving rates across China. 4 in reviewing the history of widow survival in China, this paper also adds to the literature on “missing unmarried women” (Anderson and Ray, 2015; Miguel, 2005; Oppong, 2006; Sossou, 2002). The third literature this paper draws on is the economic history literature studying the impact of textile production on the pre-modern Chinese economy in the context of the Great Divergence (Huang, 1990; Goldstone, 1996; Li and Li, 1998; Ma, 2005; Pomeranz, 2009; Wong, 2002). Several scholars have argued that the 17th and 18th centuries were a golden period for the Yangtze Delta, one of the major textile regions. Pomeranz and Li, in particular, have argued that China’s textile industry remained highly productive and profitable through the 19th century (Li and Li, 1998; Pomeranz, 2009), in face of tough competition from British textile manufactures. These studies substantiate my claim that women’s textile production was highly productive, marketized and immense in total size. China is usually considered as having historically conservative gender norms, due to its Confucian heritage. Severe son preference is often cited as evidence for historically conservative gender norms and linked to deep cultural determinants such as patrilocality. However, China also accounts for two-thirds of the richest self-made women in the world.7 Meanwhile, its neighboring country, Korea, also with a Confucian heritage, has up to 34% CEOs being women, compared to 9% in Western Europe and 5% in the US. This suggests women in those societies might have gained status in spite of patrilocality. By exploiting variation in gender gap given the presence of Confucian heritage, this paper fills in the gap to illustrate the sources of gender equality in China. This paper is organized as follows. The second section explains the historical background and lays out the conceptual framework. Section III discusses data sources and variable constructions. Section IV summarizes my baseline results, a number of robustness checks, an instrumental variable analysis and tests of alternative hypotheses. Section V demonstrates that similar effects can be found using an alternative micro-level datasets. In Section VI, I explore how the effects of pre-modern textile production first emerged and how they persisted after the decline in traditional textile production in the late nineteenth century. Section VII concludes the paper. 7 http://qz.com/529508/china-is-home-to-two-thirds-of-the-worlds-self-made-femalebillionaires/http://qz.com/529508/china-is-home-to-two-thirds-of-the-worlds-self-made-femalebillionaires/http://qz.com/529508/china-is-home-to-two-thirds-of-the-worlds-self-made-female-billionaires/ 5 II Historical Background and Conceptual Framework A Historical Background A.1 Women in Pre-modern China Similar to other patrilineal societies, women in premodern China were assigned different roles to men and took on different responsibilities in both family and society. Chinese society was also shaped in important ways by Confucian values. Confucianism has a twofold impact on attitudes on to women. On the one hand, Confucian tradition strongly disfavored women. Folk wisdom held that a family would suffer economically from the birth of a daughter.8 This cultural belief was consistent with economic reality prior to the emergence of the textile industry: daughters could not work outside home due to concern for women’s “purity”, and had to rely on family resources to survive.9 And unlike sons, a daughter would not be able to support her own parents once she became married as they had to move into the homes of their husband’s family and became an official family member there. As a result of the cost of dowries, too many daughters could cause serious financial distress to the household (Harrell, 1995; Watson and Ebrey, 1991). For the reasons described above, parents had an incentive to control the total number of daughters. Excess female mortality during infancy and childhood was widely observed.10 On the other hand, Confucianism celebrated the virtues of hard work. It therefore elevated individuals who worked hard to provide for their family, including hard working women. This provided a path for women to earn the respect due to them for their contribution to the household. Diligent productive manual labor was seen as the virtue for all women, regardless of class (Mann, 1997). Qing China (1644–1911) enjoyed a relatively high degree of social mobility, and it was a society where it was conceivable for individuals to gain social status based on higher productivity. A.2 The Cotton Revolution After agriculture, textile production was the most important economic activity in premodern societies. In China as in much of the preindustrial world, textile production was carried out by women “who spent every available moment spinning, weaving, and sewing.” (Barber, 1991). 8 In a play Qujiang Chi from early Yuan, the heroine refers to herself as pei qian huo, which literally means a money-losing proposition. The term is still used in Mainland China, Singapore, Malaysia, Taiwan, Macau and Hong Kong today. In 2007, the Yahoo dictionary in Taiwan was caught giving the English-language translation of the Chinese term pei qian huo as a. “a money-losing proposition” and b. “a girl; a daughter” (http://news.tvbs.com.tw/entry/305992 ). 9 Chow (1991) regards non-western women’s “purity” or “chastity” as both sexual and nationalistic. 10 Historian James Z. Lee and sociologist Cameron D. Campbell (2007) discovered that girls between ages one and five had a 20 percent higher mortality than boys. 6 Spinning and weaving were perceived to be a womanly skill. “Men farms and women weave” as a form of division of labor, became formalized under the state tax system dating back to 300 AD. Under the state tax system, each household was required to pay in-kind taxes in both grain and textile products. Male labor was occupied by grain production, something women did not have the comparable physical strength for. Just like other societies, women were far more productive in making cloth than in agriculture. The fiscal policies of the state solidified this gender division of labor. In early times, silk and hemp were two main fabric for clothing. Silk was the most valued of all fabric, and used in more expensive clothes. Hemp was the predominant fiber for day-to-day clothes. After 1300 new spinning and weaving technologies for processing the cotton became available. Cotton textile production was made economically viable for the first time in history (Bray, 1997; Kang, 1977). The new technologies did not develop endogenously; rather, they were borrowed from outside of the mainland. Huang Dao Po, a Shanghai native (1245–1330), learned those technologies from an ethnic group Li residing on the Hainan Island.11 On the spinning side, new technologies involved a pedal-spinning wheel with three spindles, similar to the multi-spindle design used in the Spinning Jenny invented in 18th Century England. Rather than maneuvered by hand only, new spinning machines were maneuvered by both foot and hand. Prior to the innovation, every person’s workload of weaving has to be matched by three to four people’s workload of spinning. In comparison, new spinning technologies dramatically increased the efficiency of spinning.12 Following the technological breakthrough, cotton textiles rapidly expanded in the following two centuries. Cotton quickly gained popularity over hemp in the production of day-to-day clothes. The introduction of new weaving and spinning technology allowed women to increase their productivity. They sold the surpluses to the regional and national market. By Ming times (1366–1644), the textile sector was increasingly commercialized and specialized. Cotton textiles accounted for a large portion of in-kind taxes, second only to grain. Huang (1964a) estimates that in the early 17th century, at least 1 million bolts of cotton cloth were transported through the Grand Canal as tax payments to Ming Government.13 The passage of the Single Whip Law in 1580 further promoted domestic trade and increased the market size for cotton textiles.14 Even after the mid-nineteenth century, as a significant part of spinning began to be displaced by foreign yarn, weaving remained competitive.15 By 1933, handicraft industry still made up 11 Li people today still use those technologies for textile production. The production scene is an important part of tourist attractions for the Hainan Island. 12 Other technology improvements include new techniques in cotton fluffing and crushing, and weaving insights in mixed cotton fabrics, colored fabrics and fabrics with mixed warp and weft fibers. 13 1 bolt of cotton cloth is 33.33 meters in lengh. 1 million bolts of cotton cloth were worth half a million teals at the time. 14 The Single Whip Law was initiated in the early 16th century, and promoted to the entire empire in 1580 by Zhang Juzheng (Flynn and Giráldez, 1995). 15 Rural China kept using handicraft cloth due to its lower prices and less wear and wear. Foreign merchants and consular officials in the late nineteenth-century China complained about difficulty of penetrating the Chinese 7 for 61% of the total industry output (Fairbank, 1978, pp.15-28). Women’s earnings from cotton textile production were substantial. Li (1997) shows a woman’s textile work around the year was enough to feed 2.7 people. Pomeranz (2002) provides an even more optimistic estimate:a female’s income could be four times as much as an adult male’s. Allen’s (2011) wage regressions indicate that textile workers earned a wage premium compared with workers in construction or agriculture. Women who had the skills to weave artisan cloth could earn an even higher income.16 Women in textile regions became able to earn enough to support a household independently for the first time. B Conceptual Framework Textile production following the cotton revolution, represented an new opportunity for women to earn monetary income, and contribute to household income. As the return to producing textiles was sufficiently high, women were induced to switch away from solely performing non-market domestic work or producing other fabrics at low quantities mainly for home use.17 Specialization in cotton textile production was possible because of the existence of high developed goods markets. Shiue and Keller (2007) shows the performance of markets in China and Western Europe overall was comparable in the late 18th century. Textile production at the time, shared many similarities with work in the proto-industry in other advanced pre-modern economies such as 18h century England. The following key differences deserve emphasis. (a.) Chinese households typically owned the machines rather than renting them. Households occasionally owned more than one machine and hired help. But the scale was very limited.(Fairbank, 1978) (b.) Few concurrent technology shocks occurred during the time frame (1300-1840). The cotton revolution took place in an agrarian economy, and the economy remained largely agrarian for the next sixth centuries. (c.) Though the goods market was both dense and highly sophisticated, the labor market was far from being a free labor market. Emperors in Ming and Qing institutes strict laws on labor mobility. The clan system continued to keep individuals tied to their extended families (as discussed in Greif and Tabellini, 2010, 2015). This constrained women’s ability to relocate to regions suitable for cotton textile production. (d.) Only a small number of regions had the geo-climatic conditions suitable for spinning and weaving, and especially, for weaving. Cotton textile prices, for a long time, hovered at a level that generated enough income for a skilled textile worker to support a family of four.18 (e.) A higher percentage of Chinese households owned land than British households involved in the putting-out market, especially in the interior provinces. 16 The production of artisan cloth was backed up by popular demand of weddings and funerals in pre-modern China. Its production requires both higher skills of weavers and longer hours. 17 This can be understood in the context of Pomeranz’s research on economics of respectability. In describing the role of daughters in a family, he notes that a family’s capacity to survive and to profit from its work relied upon “an optimal mix of family members of particular ages and sexes” (Pomeranz, 2005). 18 Allen (2009) shows one day’s work by a weaver in the late 17th century produced 7,684 calories, which was adequate to support a family. 8 system in the 18th century. Despite periodic increases in land concentration ratio, China had no equivalent of the movement of enclosure Britain experienced (1600-1850). The vast majority of Chinese households where women were weavers had their own land on which men had to field work. Together (b.), (c.) and (d.) ensured that prices of cotton textiles stayed reasonably high, whereas (a.) and (e.) led women to reaping most of the benefits from this revolution. Chinese women had been doing productive work prior to the cotton revolution. But cotton textile production enabled woman to take on a new role as their household’s major income earner. By the late Ming period, both unmarried and married women in many textile regions became predominantly producing for the market, and in many cases their income became the main source of family incomes. Pomeranz (2005) argues that women became more respectable due to their highly productive manual labor in textile production.19 And it is highly plausible that from the perspective of parents, it became less mentally stressful and financially costly to accept a daughter into the family as women had a potential role as productive members of the economy in their own right. In fact, women’s ability to support themselves was frequently tested in the case of widowhood: remarriage was discouraged in Ming and Qing China. However, women in textile regions found themselves well capable of remaining solvent, in the absence of their husband’s incomes. Together this evidence suggests that the rise of the textile industry since the fourteenth century constituted a significant shock to the level of women’s engagement in market activities and greatly increased their economic independence. This shock could lead to the breakdown of prior cultural beliefs concerning women’s role in providing for a family. (Bertrand et al., 2015) discusses the importance of a gender identity norm—the view that a husband should earn a higher income than wife—in marital formation and chances of divorce. They find that in fear of making more money than her future husband does, wife is more likely to give up on work in order to start a marriage. Meanwhile, dissolution of marriage is far more likely among couples who violate this important gender identity norm. Their discussion of this gender identity norm helps to understand the unique nature of the case of female empowerment driven by advanced cotton textile technologies. Due to the appearance of a new technology and the presence of both a wellfunctioning market and historically-specific government institutions, women in textile regions had unparalleled earning opportunities by the standard of past agrarian societies. As a result of this change, a large number of women in certain regions of China began to earn comparable or higher incomes than most men did. In those regions it is plausible that the gender identity norm that husband should always make more money than women broke down under the pressure of this large relative income shock. This breakdown in traditional gender identity norms could lead to the emergence of more favorable beliefs about women and a more optimistic assessment 19 Man (2011) provides a summary of depictions of female breadwinners being tough and dependable in historical accounts. Her sources include: (Chen et al., 1991; Gu, 1995; ?). In ?, Xu’s wife proudly proclaims that she single-handedly supports the family and is a ‘strong woman’, ‘she-husband’. Apparently, her husband is just passionate about literary writing and paintings, and clueless to how to make both ends meet. 9 of the fates of prospective daughters. The evolution of gender norms following a long period of taking a more prominent role in providing for a family, can play a crucial role in gender gap and women’s well-being in presentday China. Viewing general norms as a complex of nexus of different beliefs and attitudes concerning the relative status of women, it is sufficient to note that gender norms are both perpetuated from generation to generation (as shown theoretically by Bisin and Verdier (2001) and as discussed empirically by numerous studies in sociology and economics (Moen et al., 1997; Vella and Farré, 2007) and also shaped by the attitudes of others in society (Burda et al., 2007). Both mechanisms generate cultural persistence and can explain why cultural values, once established, can be difficult to dislodge. Inherited gender attitudes shape a wide range of outcomes today. The most important one I focus on in this paper is sex ratio at birth. When parents today make a decision as to whether to have a boy or a girl, they do not have complete information on the future prospects of a boy or a girl in contemporary world. They instead resort to general beliefs about whether boys or girls are morel likely to thrive in society and to favor the family.20 Sex ratio imbalances are an important indicator for differential values being assigned to each sex and thus a good indicator for women’s status in society.21 These cultural beliefs are particularly important under a one-child policy regime and can be exercised at low costs given the availability of sex-selection technology. To sum up, I argue that pre-modern textile production has a strong, persistent impact on gender roles, gender norms and gender equality today. In particular, I hypothesize a relationship between pre-modern textile production and gender equality in contemporary China. I theorize that women’s use of a productive technology increases their social status and the desirability of daughters. Women’s increasing relative contribution to household income generated new norms about women’s role in the household as a main breadwinner. In textile regions people developed the belief that women can protect families from destitution and allowed them to pay their taxes just as effectively as men. The reformed gender norms and beliefs can persist even though the economy has moved out of traditional cotton textile production. 20 Altruistic parents who care about whether or not their children have fruitful lives will prefer to have boys if they live in a society where women are treated less well. 21 President’s Commission for the Study of Ethical Problems in Medicine and Biomedical and Behavior Research of the United States in 1983 states that there is no evidence that amniocentesis is being sought widely to determine fetal sex. Surveys of parents and prospective parents indicate, however, a preference for sons (especially as the first-born child). If it became an accepted practice, the selection of sons in preference to daughters would be yet another means of assigning greater social value to one sex over the other and perpetuating the historical discrimination. 10 III Data I construct my main variable, pre-modern cotton textile production, from thousands of local gazetteers published in historical times. I also construct contemporary measures of gender norms and gender equality, historical and contemporary county characteristics from a large number of modern censuses, historical sources and GIS files, and climatic and geographic characteristics from the Climate Research Unit of University of East Anglia, FAO and NASA. From the digital world map collection of Harvard University, CHGIS, I obtain shape files that contain historical characteristics for the counties within China. For modern outcome variables, I use the countylevel National Population Censuses (1990, 2000, 2010) and the 2004 Industrial Census from the China Geo Explorer, the Chinese City Statistical Yearbooks, individual-level census data (1982, 1990) from IPUMS-International, and Chinese General Social Surveys (2005, 2010). To construct large political and economic shock variables as well as past outcome variables, I tap into local gazetteers and make use of economic censuses and statistics complied by missionaries in the early twentieth century. In this section, I mainly focus on data used in my county-level analysis, where a total of 1535 counties, 198 prefectures, 15 provinces, and 8 regions are used. Data sources for other historical, geographic and contemporary variables can be found in the data appendix. A Explanatory Variable: Pre-Modern Cotton Textiles Based on local gazetteers between 1368 and 1840, I construct an indicator variable on pre-modern cotton textile production at a county level. Local gazetteers were published by prefecture governments and county governments, containing information on local produces and manufactured products. I go through county-level and prefecture-level gazetteers to extract information on cotton textiles.22 It is possible a county that started textile production first would see a larger impact of textile production in shaping values and beliefs. However, the way local gazetteers were organized does not allow me to pinpoint the starting point of production by county. Due to similar data limitations, I cannot examine the quantitative dimension of textile production by county. I also do not have the full knowledge of the quality of cotton textiles at the county level. As quantity produced and quality can be potential sources of heterogeneity in the treatment effect, the estimates should be interpreted as average treatment effect of historical textile production. To obtain an estimate of the distribution of then textile-producing counties and prefectures across China today, I map historical locations of cotton textile production into a map of China in 2000. Due to name and boundary changes of historical counties and prefectures, I resort to time-series maps of Chinese counties and prefectures to first determine historical locations 22 In the data collection process, I mainly refer to the section on local specialties (shi huo zhi ) for evidence of cotton textile production. 11 of cotton textile production. To be specific, I match county names in the source with county names in a point shape file comprising times-series counties, prefecture names in the source with prefecture names in a a polygon shape file comprising time-series prefectures. Finally, I spatially join both times-series maps with the county shape file corresponding with the 2000 population census to obtain a county-level estimate of cotton textile production. Figure 1 displays the location of pre-modern textile production. Figure 1: Explanatory Variable: Pre-Modern Cotton Textiles B Main Outcome Variable: Sex Ratio at Birth I use sex ratio at birth from the 2000 Census.23 Data on sex ratios at birth are available at the county level. My main outcome variable is sex ratio at birth.24 As the distribution of raw sex ratios is entirely skewed towards the left, I use a common data transformation technique to create z cores of raw sex ratios. There is considerable variation in the extent of sex ratios. In 2000, at the county level, sex ratios at birth range from 81:100 to 196:100. With the exclusion of five autonomous regions, I still 23 The reason for mainly using sex ratio at birth in the 2000 census is that (a.) sex selection technologies were widely available (Chen et al., 2013; Ebenstein, 2010). (b.) regional variation in one-child policy was limited to urban-rural differences. After 2000, some counties began to be experiment a two-child policy for parents that were both only-child. (c.) marriage rates were still high. Voluntary infertility was relatively rare. (d.) data quality of the 2000 census is reportedly higher. 24 Alternatively, I can derive a measure of logged form of the deviation of sex ratio at birth from the normal sex ratio, and I get very similar results using the alternative measure. 12 find a wide range of sex ratios (92:100 to 193:100) across counties. Figure 2 shows sex ratio at birth in seven quantiles. Figure 2: Main Outcome Variable: Sex Ratio at Birth A male-biased sex ratio is a crucial indicator of gender bias. China has had the most unbalanced sex ratios in East Asia for the past decade. In the 2000 Census, the national average sex ratio at birth is 118:100, i.e. every 118 boys were born to every 100 girls. Prior to the one-child policy, people resorted to higher-parity births to ensure male offspring. A major problem for identifying the magnitude of gender bias in this setting is that the characteristics associated with low fertility are often correlated with characteristics associated with gender equality. Though stopping rules can distort sex ratios, the distortions become smaller as number of children increases. As a result, places with high fertility and high levels of gender inequality may not necessarily have a more distorted sex ratio than a place with lower fertility but low levels of gender inequality. When levels of fertility are imposed rather than chosen, the relationship between gender bias and sex ratio not only becomes more pronounced, but also more comparable across China. In the 1980s, the state first initiated its one-child policy. Families have since lost much of their autonomy to ensure male offspring through the channel of higher-parity births.25 As sex-selective technology became widely available after late 1980s, families started to rely on ultrasound and other technology to secure a son in their first birth.26 The strategy of sex selection at a lower25 One-child policy was finally phased out on October 29, 2015. http://www.bbc.com/news/world-asia34665539 26 Depending on the household registration status, urban Chinese were allowed to have one child only, whereas 13 parity birth causes sex ratios within a family to be artificially chosen, contributing to sex ratio imbalances on a much larger scale at the aggregate level (Ebenstein, 2010). C Baseline Controls In the baseline regression, I control for contemporary variables including current per capita GDP, share of agricultural workforce, share of non-agricultural household registration, share of ethnic population and provincial capital, historical variables including agricultural suitability, proximity to the Grand Canal or the Yangtze River and treaty port, as well as a set of geographic variables, such as latitude, longitude, ruggedness and distance to coast. I obtain most of contemporary variables from the 2000 Census. The current per capita GDP is based on the map “2000 county GDP” at the digital map collection of Harvard University. Historical controls include agricultural suitability, proximity to the Grand Canal or the Yangtze River and treaty port status. Agricultural suitability data are downloaded from the FAO website, used to proxy a county’s agricultural productivity. Rice and tea suitability used to test the competing hypotheses are also from FAO. Proximity to the Grand Canal or Yangtze is constructed from CHGIS files.27 Pre-1300 commercial tax quota and historical courier routes used to test competing hypotheses are similarly from the digital map collection of Harvard University. Distance to the nearest coast and ruggedness are constructed from NASA data. To account for cultural and endowment differences across regions, I use Skinner socioeconomic macroregions (Skinner and Berman, Skinner and Berman) as region fixed effects. D Descriptive Statistics I construct my data set as follows. I exclude five autonomous regions, as well as autonomous prefectures and counties in other provinces, that historically comprise ethnic minorities. Descriptive statistics for the county-level analysis can be found in Table 1. Table 1 gives an overview of the key variables in the main sample. A total of 1513 counties are included. Sex ratio at birth is for Year 2000. Most modern variables are for 2000 as well, unless otherwise noted. About 40% of the counties had some form of cotton textile production before 1840. Average sex ratio at at birth for 2000 is 118.9 boys per 100 girls, with a standard deviation of 14.2. Roughly 10% of the counties are on a major trade network (Grand Canal or Yangtze). An average county has a value of 4.398 on the humidity-for-weaving index, with a standard deviation of 2.277. rural Chinese were allowed to have a second child if the first-born was a girl 27 Due to lower transportation costs, a good number of counties located near the Yangtze River and the Grand Canal produced textiles in pre-modern China. Huang (1964b) emphasizes the importance of the Grand Canal in Ming China, confirming that many counties famous for textile production were located in the Grand Canal area, and the size of trade was considerable. This could pose a challenge to my identification strategy, which I will discuss in the next section. 14 Table 1: Summary Statistics: County-Level Analysis Variable Sex ratio at birth Pre-modern textiles Mean 119 0.42 Std. Dev. 14.273 0.494 Min. 91.622 0 Max. 193.16 1 N 1535 1535 Logged share of ethnic minorities Logged per capita GDP Logged per capita GDP2 Logged share of agriculture workforce Logged share of non-agriculture registration Provincial capital Treaty port Agricultural suitability On the Grand Canal or Yangtze Log (ruggedness+1) Logged distance to coast Latitude Longitude -0.88 13.246 176.704 3.922 2.845 0.102 0.123 -4.309 0.089 1.193 5.395 31.805 114.224 1.608 1.117 27.184 0.985 0.701 0.302 0.329 1.915 0.285 0.792 1.319 4.801 4.285 -4.605 3.472 12.056 -2.408 1.105 0 0 -8 0 0.078 0.083 20.42 101.584 4.544 18.154 329.583 4.57 4.531 1 1 -1 1 3.083 7.07 41.773 122.391 1533 1530 1530 1535 1535 1535 1535 1535 1535 1535 1535 1535 1535 4.423 2.283 1.562 8.333 1535 Yangtze Delta Net in migration Sex ratio, aged 5-9 Sex ratio, aged 1-4 Sex ratio, aged 1-4, 2010 Sex ratio at birth, 2010 Women’s years of schooling Men’s years of schooling Years of schooling Women’s years of schooling, 2010 Men’s years of schooling, 2010 Women’s illiteracy rate, 1990 Men’s illiteracy rate, 1990 0.173 0.012 115.15 121.9 119.046 117.65 7.072 8.164 7.632 8.427 9.326 0.343 0.138 0.378 0.296 10.103 16.352 11.472 10.813 1.023 0.856 0.92 1.141 0.951 0.108 0.062 0 -0.293 95.035 91.655 92.004 86.400 4.48 6.09 5.520 5.560 6.07 0.095 0.018 1 4.733 165.582 204.068 161.656 176.744 11.28 11.91 11.48 12.85 13.39 0.748 0.422 1535 1535 1535 1535 1461 1461 1535 1535 1535 1461 1461 1126 1126 Rice suitability Tea suitability Log (#textile companies+1) #courier routes Logged (Commercial tax+1), 1077 Log (communicants per 10,000+1) 5.937 88.131 2.79 0.434 2.631 1.53 1.739 132.13 1.626 0.841 3.746 1.095 1 0 0 0 0 0 9 287 7.87 6 10.837 5.254 1503 1503 1535 1535 1535 1038 Humidity-for-weaving index 15 IV County-Level OLS estimates Having constructed county-level measures of pre-modern textile production, I can examine the relationship between pre-modern textiles and gender equality in present-day China. I begin by examining variation at the county level. My outcome variable is sex ratio at birth. I test my hypothesis by estimating the following equation: G C Sex ratio at birth = α + βPre-modern textilesc + XH c Ω + Xc Λ + Xc Π + p , (1) where c denotes a county. Pre-modern textilesc is my measure of pre-modern textile production G C at a county level. XH c is a vector of historical controls, and Xc and Xc are vectors of geographical and contemporary controls respectively, each measured at the county level. H XG c and Xc are intended to capture geographic and historical characteristics that may have been correlated with pre-modern textiles and may still affect present-day outcomes. I control for whether the county is on the Grand Canal or the Yangtze River, the major trade networks at the time, as how pre-modern textiles were located was likely influenced by access to market. To account for geographic differences across counties that may be correlated with openness to trade, I include in XG c logged distance to coast and logged (ruggedness+1). As historical China was an agrarian economy, I include in XG c agricultural suitability as a proxy for agricultural productivity as well as latitude and longitude. To account for an external intervention in recent history–the establishment of treaty ports by western powers—I also include “treaty port status” as a control. To deal with norms such as patrilocality and concern for women’s purity (Jayachandran, 2015) and other differences across regions, I include regional fixed effects corresponding to Skinner’s Socioeconomic Macroregions. Skinner’s Socioeconomic Macroregions capture deep-rooted differences across regions, and bisect provincial boundaries in many cases. The contemporary control variables XC c include the natural log of a county’s per capita GDP measured in 2000 and its squared term, share of agriculture workforce, share of non-agricultural household registration, share of ethnic population, governance status of the prefecture containing the county, governance status of the county, and provincial capital status.28 I use share of non-agricultural household registration to capture an important source of variation in the one-child policy.29 Governance status of the prefecture containing the county, governance status 28 The logic behind the inclusion of the squared term of log per capita GDP can be found in Chung and Gupta (2007). Chinese prefectures and counties underwent institutional reforms after 1982. Level of political centralization started to vary across prefectures and counties. I use two categorical variables to characterize governance status and degree of centralization of a prefecture or a county. Governance status of the prefecture takes the value of one when the prefecture has no centralized government; zero when it has a centralized government. Governance status of the county takes one when it is governed by the prefecture-level government, two when it is self-governed, and three when it is governed by the province-level government. 29 While the one-child policy was strictly enforced among Chinese citizens on non-agricultural registration status, a more relaxed version of the one-child policy was enforced among those on agricultural household registration status. 16 Table 2: Pre-Modern Textiles and Sex Ratio Imbalances: OLS Results Sex ratio at birth (2) (3) (1) Pre-modern textiles Log per capita GDP Log per capita GDP2 Logged share of agriculture workforce Logged share of non-agriculture registration Provincial capital Historical controls Geographic controls Region FE Province FE Observations Adjusted R2 Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ (4) -3.311∗ (1.754) 2.064∗ (0.988) -0.144∗∗ (0.0487) 0.736 (0.685) -5.595∗∗∗ (1.494) 3.060 (2.058) Yes Yes Yes No -4.117∗∗ (1.706) -3.404∗ (1.691) -3.555∗ (1.686) Yes Yes Yes Yes 0.508 (0.686) -5.653∗∗∗ (1.510) 2.009 (2.090) Yes Yes Yes Yes 0.764 (1.986) Yes Yes Yes Yes 1528 0.360 1535 0.284 1533 0.353 1535 0.310 p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 Notes: The table reports the impact of pre-modern textiles on sex ratio imbalances. The unit of observation is a county in 2000 Census. The dependent variable is sex ratio at birth. Column 1 reports estimates with all controls along with region and province effects. “Historical controls” are treaty port status, agriculture suitability, and whether a county was on the Grand Canal or the Yangtze River (major trade network). “Geographic controls” are log of ruggedness plus 1, log of distance to coast, latitude, longitude and their interaction. Column 2 shows estimates when all contemporary controls are dropped. Column 3 excludes log per capita GDP on the grounds of potential endogeniety. Column 4 drops most contemporary variables such as share of ethnic population, share of agriculture workforce and share of non-agriculture registration but keeps provincial capital. Robust standard errors are clustered at the province level. 17 of the county, provincial capital is intended to capture differences in enforcement of one-child policy, political control and government-led growth. Both share of non-agricultural household registration and governance status could have an effect on sex ratios through one-child policy (Ebenstein, 2010). In addition, as there is a clear ethnic and cultural component in son preference, I control for share of ethnic minority population to reduce composition bias.30 OLS estimates of equation (1) including above controls are reported in Table 2. Column 1 reports estimates with all controls along with region and province fixed effects. Column 2, 3 and 4 reports specifications with potentially endogenous variables excluded. Column 2 shows estimates when all modern controls are excluded, Column 3 shows estimates when per capita GDP and its squared terms are excluded from the specification, and Column 4 shows estimates when only provincial capital is included as a contemporary control. The estimates show that in counties with pre-modern textile production, fewer girls are missing today. The coefficient estimates are both statistically significant and economically meaningful. Based on the estimates from Column 1, one unit increase in pre-modern textile production is associated with a decrease of sex ratio at birth by 1.62 boys per hundred girls (1.62=3.31*0.49). As I drop all modern controls, the size of the coefficient further increases to -4.117, suggesting that some of the modern controls are themselves outcomes of pre-modern textile production. Column 3 suggests the strength of the coefficient for textile production does not depend on whether I control for per capita GDP.31 In Column 4, I drop most of modern controls but keep provincial capital status. The coefficient is rather similar to what is in Column 1-3. This will be the baseline model for the rest of the county-level analysis . A Robustness checks A.1 Subsamples I first check the robustness of my results to the use of alternative samples. Motivated by the fact that the Yangtze Delta is of special importance to Chinese economy both historically and contemporarily, I test to see if my results are robust to the control or the omission of three provinces (Jiangsu, Zhejiang & Shanghai) from the sample. Next, I look at counties with different rates of migration. Historically, labor mobility was low due to the control of the clan system. In modern China, the speed of migration has picked up. Gender norms in the less developed regions of China could have been strengthened if individuals with more progressive gender norms are more likely to move to developed areas for a better life. Hence my results could be biased if textile locations are correlated with unobservable 30 Autonomous counties and prefectures, which are predominately resided and governed by ethnic minorities, are already excluded from the main sample. 31 Though large sex ratio imbalances are a relatively new phenomenon in China, per capita GDP could still have already been affected that the sex ratio, i.e. it is possible that per capita GDP is partly endogenous to sex ratio imbalances (Wei and Zhang, 2011). 18 characteristics of counties that attract many modern migrants. For robustness, I control for net in-migration, or omit counties with positive net in-migration. Table A.1 in the appendix summarizes the results. The coefficient estimates are relatively stable across the columns. Coefficient estimates are greater for counties outside of Yangtze Delta or areas that have no net in-migration. A.2 Sex Ratio at Birth from More Years In the main analysis, I focus on sex ratio at birth in the 2000 Census. A natural question is whether the same pattern holds for years within the close range of Year 2000. Based on 2000, 2010 census data, I construct two additional variables from the 2000 Census: sex ratio for aged 1 to 4, sex ratio for aged 5 to 9; and two variables from the 2010 Census: sex ratio at birth, sex ratio for aged 1-4. I find coefficients of pre-modern textiles in Table A.2 are fairly close to coefficients in Column 5 of Table 2. The coefficient of sex ratio at birth for 2010 is much smaller and not statistically significant. I attribute this to the data reporting procedures used in the 2010 Census.32 There is no reason to believe that the true sex ratio at birth suddenly dropped for the 2010 cohort, but not for cohorts 2005-2009. Overall, I find pre-modern textile production affects the cohorts born after 1990 in a highly consistent way. The relationship between pre-modern textiles and sex ratio at birth revealed by the 2000 census is unlikely just a fluke. A.3 Other Gender Outcomes Table A.3 examines alternative gender outcomes. I find pre-modern textile production also predicts women’s educational attainment. In 2000, pre-modern textile production is associated with an increase of 0.167 years of schooling for women. The coefficient is reduced to 0.106 after controlling for men’s education. Coefficients are very similar for 2010. Pre-modern textile production is also associated with a reduction of 3.1 percentage points in female illiteracy rates, or 1.14 percentage points when male illiteracy rate is controlled for with a p-value of 0.11.33 B IV Estimation A potential concern with the OLS estimates is that the counties that were textile producers may have a higher likelihood of adopting textile technologies. It is possible that counties that were economically more developed were more likely to have adopted textile technologies, and counties that were closer to the market or transportation routes were more likely to sustain its production and make greater profits. If these counties were more commercial and had “modern” 32 Due to a booming migrant population, the 2010 Census resorted to the recording method of “recording every individual encountered”. Double counting of the 200-million floating population became highly probable events. News sources suggest this method might have opened the door to data manipulation by lower-level governments, due to the political pressure on “keep the sex ratio at birth below 120” emerging after 2000. http://blog.people.com.cn/article/1354459332295.html 33 For the 1990 Census, though data on women’s education are available by educational level, they are not aggregated to the “year of schooling” variable. 19 gender norms, this would bias the OLS estimates away from zero. Though a set of variables (mainly overall agricultural suitability, distance to the major trade network, distance to the coast, ruggedness and regional fixed effects) have been included in the main specification and its variants, I am unable to address likely issues caused by unobservable characteristics, such as attitudes towards women prior to textile production. Besides, due to imperfect data on premodern textile production, some of the coefficient estimates can suffer attenuation bias due to measurement error. To derive an exogenous source in determining the location of textile production within China I use climate data. An important determinant for the location of textile industry is geo-climatic conditions. Among all contributing factors, scientists, engineers and industry experts highlight the importance of relative humidity in producing textiles. In a report on the textile industry in China (1909), the word “humidity” occurs more than 100 times, suggesting the pivotal role of humidity in the textile industry. Climatic conditions were a crucial determinant in the geographic variation in spinning and weaving in pre-modern China. Spinning and weaving far more likely to occur in humid counties. Even when spinning and weaving were carried on relentlessly, less humid counties often failed to produce as high quality cotton fabrics. A lack of humidity severely hampered a county’s performance in the high-ended markets, as top-notch cotton cloth could only be weaved when relative humidity was close to or greater than 70%.34 Apart from average relatively humidity, variance in humidity could also affect production decisions. Textiles could be produced much more efficiently during parts of the day, and parts of the year that were comparatively humid. For places that experience greater variance in humidity within the day, the number of hours available for textile production could be quite limited, regardless of the average relative humidity. A textile machine represented a large fixed cost. For a family the decision to own textile machinery the total number of hours possible for textile production would be a key consideration. The Climate Research Unit of University of East Anglia provides 30-year monthly average relatively humidity data across 10 arc-minute by 10 arc-minute grid cells globally. I extract relative humidity values on the basis of x, y coordinates. I construct a relative humidity variable at the county level by averaging over all relative humidity values within a polygon that represents a county. I then construct a humidity-for-weaving index as follows. First, every county receives a score ranging from 1 to 5 for each month, based on the distance between actual relative humidity for the month and suitable humidity for weaving.35 Second, I add up monthly scores. I get a 34 Gazetteer data suggest that a relatively small number of counties were able to produce cotton textiles in pre-modern China. By 1840, up to 40% of the counties participated in textile production, varying in quantity and quality. 35 In the absence of modern humidification facilities, hardly any textiles can be produced when relative humidity drops below 60%, and that the benefit of moist air starts to wear off once relative humidity exceeds 80%, i.e. there is a non-linear relationship between relative humidity and suitability for textile production. To account for non-linearity in the impact of relative humidity on historical textile production, I set the lower-bound relative humidity for feasible production to be 60%, and make it take a value of ”5” if actual relative humidity is below 20 number ranging from 12 to 60 for each county, with 12 being the most suitable, and 60 being the least suitable. Third, I take the inverse of the total score to build an humidity-for-weaving index where suitability increases in its value. This index can be seen as approximating the number of months available for production with a gradient to quality and efficiency. Figure 4 shows the distribution of humidity-for-weaving index at a county level. Darker shades represent higher relative humidity and hence, higher weaving suitability. Missing values are shaded white. Figure 3: IV: Humidity-for-Weaving Index Ideally, this variable would represent the hours available for textile production. In practice, data do not exist on the relative humidity for any particular day, let alone variance within a day. Hence I restrict my focus on the number of months humid enough for textile production as demonstrated above. A benefit of having a relative humidity index specific to weaving is that I can extract useful information from relative humidity while avoiding additional biases. Table 3 shows the constructed instrument is correlated with pre-modern textile production, and yet, uncorrelated with factors normally associated with relative humidity, such as overall agricultural suitability, tea suitability and tea suitability. I begin my IV estimation by testing the relationship between my humidity-for-weaving index and pre-modern textile production. As my textile variable is a binary treatment, I opt for a Probit-2sls that uses a Probit model for the first stage. Panel A of Table 4 shows the estimates from the first stage: humidity-for-weaving index is positively correlated with pre-modern textile the cutoff. Once above 60%, a county will be scored on a lower number as its relative humidity increases, i.e. ”4” for 61%-65%, ”3” for 66%-70%, ”2” for 71%-75%, ”1” for 76% or above. 21 Table 3: The Impact of Humidity-for-Weaving on Other Outcomes Humidity-for-weaving index Baseline controls Observations Adjusted R2 Pseudo R2 (1) Logit Pre-modern textiles (2) Logit Provincial capital (3) OLS Agricultural suitability (4) Logit On the major trade network (5) OLS Tea suitability (6) OLS Rice suitability 0.152∗∗ (0.0595) Yes -0.118 (0.0728) Yes 0.00328 (0.0676) Yes 0.0989 (0.0869) Yes 3.275 (4.540) Yes -0.00851 (0.0755) Yes 1524 1524 1535 0.650 1045 1503 0.800 1503 0.660 0.420 Standard errors in parentheses ∗ 0.246 p < 0.10, ∗∗ 0.296 p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 Notes: The table reports falsification tests of humidity-for-weaving index. The unit of observation is a county in the 2000 Census. The dependent variables are pre modern textiles, provincial capital status, agricultural suitability, distance to the grand Canal or Yangtze (on the major trade network), tea suitability and rice suitability. All controls in Column 4 of Table 2 are included, with the exception of the one that happens to be the dependent variable in the very specification. Region and province fixed effects are included in all specifications. Robust standard errors are clustered at the provincial level. production. Second-stage results are reported in Panel B. Column 1 contains my OLS estimates. Column 2 report my IV estimate with humidity-for-weaving index being the instrument. My IV estimate is that a one-standard deviation increase in pre-modern textiles leads to a reduction of sex ratio at birth by 3.8 boys per hundred girls (3.8=7.61*0.49). This is slightly greater than the OLS estimate. The increase in coefficient estimates can be partly explained by the IV estimate by the removal of attenuation bias due to the use of better measured data. C Competing Hypotheses C.1 Tea and Rice Tea and rice production were two other economic activities in which women often participated. Locations of tea and rice production, in some occasions, overlapped with textile production. Qian (2008) finds a short-term increase in tea prices can enhance women’s household bargaining power and increase the share of surviving girls. Perhaps either tea or rice production could affect gender norms and shape attitudes towards women in the long run and also happen to be correlated with textile production? I include tea and rice suitability in Column 1 and 2 of Table A.4 and find no significant change in the coefficient of pre-modern textiles. Rice suitability, in fact, is positively correlated with sex ratio at birth, confirming the negative role of agricultural production in women’s status (Hansen et al., 2015). 22 Table 4: Pre-Modern Textiles and Sex Ratio at Birth: Instrumental Variable Analysis First Stage Dependent variable: pre-modern textiles (1) (2) Humidity-for-weaving index N/A Baseline controls Region FE Province FE Yes Yes Yes 0.081 ∗∗ (0.036) Yes Yes Yes Second Stage Dependent variable: sex ratio at birth (1) (2) Pre-modern textiles Same controls as in the first stage Observations Standard errors in parentheses -3.555∗ (1.686) Yes -7.617∗∗ (3.993) Yes 1535 ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, 1524 ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 Notes: The table reports IV estimates. The unit of observation is a county in the 2000 Census. Humidity-for-weaving index is used as an instrument. The dependent variable is sex ratio at birth. Baseline controls are the same as in Column 1 and 2 of Table 2. Column 1 contains OLS estimates. Column 2 report IV estimates. Region and province fixed effects are included in all specifications. Robust standard errors are clustered at the province level. 23 C.2 Pre-1300 Commerce Overall economic development and commercialization, prior to the cotton revolution, could have both promoted cotton textile production and given rise to progressive gender norms. I include the pre-1300 commercial tax quota in Column 3 of Table A.4 and find only a small increase in the size of coefficient of pre-modern textiles. Coefficients of pre-1300 commercial tax and its square term are insignificant. Coefficient signs indicate a likely non-linear relationship between past commerce and women’s status.36 In contrast to Bertocchi and Bozzano (2013), I do not find past commerce per se to be consistently conducive to the status of women. C.3 State Presence The history of pre-modern textiles suggests that the state played a key role in the relationship between cotton textile production and women. As I have noted the default norm that women worked in textile production was partly due to long-standing state policies that required in-kind taxes and which were most consistent with the paradigm of “men farm and women weave”. In addition to being used in lieu of other goods for taxation purposes, cotton textiles were important for military purposes, and were widely used to clothe the imperial army. Also, the state could have also influenced the local adoption of new textile technologies by state promotion. Despite the ubiquitous nature of today’s Chinese state, one might still suspect there is a degree of persistence in state presence. A strong state presence could mean better enforcements of major state policies, such as the one-child policy or the compulsory education reform. Therefore, past state presence can simultaneously influence locations of pre-modern textile production and gender outcomes in contemporary China. Historically, courier routes in China were used and managed by the central government for conveyors and messengers to fast deliver high-profile news (Yang et al., 2006). I include historical courier routes in Column 4 of Table A.4 as a proxy for state presence. I find state presence is negatively correlated with sex ratio at birth. Greater state presence does improve relative outcomes of women. However, the coefficient of pre-modern textiles barely changes when historical courier routes are controlled for, suggesting that the two effects are most likely independent of each other. C.4 Industrial Persistence An obvious hypothesis is that pre-modern textiles could shape gender outcomes through the persistence in sectoral composition. With the availability of modern humidification technologies, there is little reason to think textile companies continue to locate only in humid areas. However, being in a naturally humid area might still attract modern textile companies due to cost-saving considerations. In addition, human capital accumulated in pre-modern production might find its 36 This is not overly surprising given the well-documented U-shaped female labor force function (Goldin and Schultz, 1995). Rich merchant families were more able to sacrifice labor incomes of daughters’ or wives’. Footbinding, for example, started from the very well-off families as female members of those families had no need to work. 24 ways into modern textile production, attracting companies to locate close to where talents are.37 In Column 5 of Table A.4 , I include number of textile companies as a control. I find the scale of modern textile production indeed reduces sex ratio imbalances. The size of the coefficient of interest falls by a quarter, but remains highly significant. This suggests pre-modern textile production does not affect women’s status in contemporary China solely through the channel of modern textile production. Other explanations would be required. V Micro-Level Analysis I turn to a micro-level analysis that examines variation in women’s representation in highpowered professions and women’s position in the family across individuals, using the 1990 Population Census available at the IPUMS - International. The time frame of the 1990 Census allows an investigate gender norms just before the planned economy era reached an end. An additional feature of this census is that they are particularly suitable for studying gender outcomes prior to mass sex selection.38 The 1990 Census also has quite high data quality in the sense that the size of the floating population was negligible at the time. I construct the following two outcomes of interest: holding political or managerial positions and head of the household.39 I construct a binary variable for “holding political or managerial positions”. The variable takes the value of 1 for “legislators, senior officials and management”, 0 for other occupations. Missing values are assigned in the case that an individual is listed as “NIU (not in universe)”. The “head of the household variable” takes the value of 1 for individuals listed as “head of the household”, 0 individuals listed as “spouse”. Table A.5 in the appendix describes my sample based on the 1990 Census.40 For an average prefecture, 41% of its population live in places with pre-modern textile production. 1.7% of the individuals hold political or managerial positions. 56% of the individuals are head of the household; the rest 44% are listed as a spouse. 37 In this case, current textile production is an intermediate outcome of pre-modern textile production, a.k.a an endogenous variable. 38 In the mass sex selection era, as part of the gender bias has already been reflected in sex selection, outcomes of the survivors—a pre-selected group— might not reflect the full extent of gender inequalities in society. Lin et al. (2014); Hu and Schlosser (2015) 39 The US Census used to have the “Head of the household” and an accordant variable “Relationship to head of the household”. But it has now switched to “Person 1” and “Relationship to first person listed on the questionnaire”. https://www.census.gov/history/www/throught hed ecades/indexo fq uestions/1980p opulation.html I interpret wife heading the household for a currently married couple to be an indicator of her power in the family. 40 Geographic coverage of my 1990 Census sample is comparable to that of the 2000 Census sample used in my county-level analysis. More than 98% of the individuals within the geographic coverage are Han Chinese, higher than the national average of 93%. This is to be expected as five autonomous regions and autonomous counties are not included in my analysis. In my micro analysis, I further restrict the sample to Han Chinese individuals. 25 My estimation equation is yi,p =α + βPre-modern textilesp + θFemalei + ζPre-modern textilesp × Femalei I C G + XH p Ω + Xp Λ + Xp Π + Xi Γ + i,p , (2) where p denotes a prefecture.41 My outcome variables are “holding political or managerial positions” and “head of the household”. Pre-modern textilesp is my prefecture-level measure of pre-modern textile production.42 My variable of interest is the interaction term between premodern textiles and female. If pre-modern textiles were effective in shaping gender norms in C G favor of women, I should see the interaction term being significant. XH p , Xp and Xp are the same controls as in the county-level analysis.43 XIi Γ denotes current individual-level controls: age group, marital status, employment status and literacy. Robust standard errors are clustered at the prefecture level for all specifications. Estimation results based on logit regressions are reported in Table 5. Coefficient estimates of pre-modern textiles interacted with female are statistically significant for all columns. This is consistent with the hypothesis that pre-modern textile production enhances women’s position in society and at home. Coefficients of pre-modern textiles suggest pre-modern textile production has little effect on men’s probability to take political or managerial positions, suggesting that there is no systematic difference between pre-modern textile production and availability of political or managerial positions in general. In all specifications, women are far less likely to either take political or managerial positions, or be the head of the household. This suggests that despite the socialist laws in favor of gender equality and the rich set of political and economic tools available to the state during the planned economy era, women’s position in society and at home was still not fully equitable with men’s. In Column 1 and 2, I find pre-modern textile increases women’s probability of holding political or managerial positions. As I restrict the sample to individuals living in a households with at least one married couple and who are currently married in Column 3 and 4, the finding should be interpreted as a wife heading the household rather than denoting female-headed households comprising women who have never married or divorced women. 41 In the IPUMS 1990 census data, individual residence is only recorded at the prefecture level. I aggregate the county-level indicator of pre-modern textile production to the prefecture level weighted by county population. A prefecture unit is constructed from counties belonging to the sample used in the county-level analysis. 43 C Xp are county-level census data aggregated to the prefecture level weighted by county population. For XC p most controls from the census year 2000 are replaced with controls from the census year 1990.GDP per capita 2000 is replaced by GDP per capita 1989. 42 26 Table 5: Pre-Modern Textiles and Status of Women : 1990 Census Political or Managerial Position (1) (2) Pre-modern textiles Head of the Household (3) (4) -0.00767 (0.0913) Female -1.991∗∗∗ (0.0776) Pre-modern textiles 0.218∗ × Female (0.118) Individual controls No Contemporary controls Yes Historical controls Yes Geographic controls Yes Region FE Yes Province FE Yes -0.0130 (0.0798) -2.018∗∗∗ (0.0795) 0.232∗ (0.122) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes -0.313 (0.195) -5.890∗∗∗ (0.232) 0.629∗ (0.375) No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes -0.314 (0.194) -5.794∗∗∗ (0.233) 0.648∗ (0.372) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations Pseudo R2 2666125 0.195 1815655 0.685 1815655 0.686 2666125 0.172 Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 Notes: The table reports the impact of pre-modern textiles on women’s position in society at home. The unit of observation is a individual in the 1990 Census. The dependent variable is binary. All estimates are based on logit regressions. Contemporary, historical and geographic controls are the same as in Table 2, but contempoary controls here are from the census year 1990 instead. Individual controls include age group, marital status, employment status and literacy. Only married individuals are included in the sample for Column 3 and 4. Robust standard errors are clustered at the prefecture level. 27 VI The Emergence and Persistence of Gender Equality A The Emergence of Gender Equality A.1 Widow Survival: Changing Notions of Women’s Role in Society Unlike the Europe Marriage Pattern (De Moor and Van Zanden, 2010; Voigtländer and Voth, 2013), pre-modern China featured universal marriage and early marriage. Unmarried and married women alike had limited opportunities to participate in society on their own. However, widows were given a certain amount of autonomy in making economic decisions for the household, despite the overall conservative family and property ownership laws in pre-modern China (Afeng, 2002). However, prior to the cotton revolution, women typically lacked the means to support themselves after their husband’s death. Remarriage was quite common. Things took another turn after the 11th century. Influenced by Song-Ming Neo-Confucianism first developed in the Song Dynasty (960–1279), on one hand, inheritance laws became more unfriendly to women, creating barriers for women to inherit wealth from their deceased husband; on the other hand, remarriage became stigmatized. Both changes greatly limited options available to widows. The difficult circumstances faced by widows are not unique to pre-modern China. Widows in developing countries today continue to face more or less similar problems: widows not only lose the main breadwinner of the household, but also are restricted access to economic resources due to property ownership laws and employment norms. Many studies document the role of widowhood in excess mortality for unmarried adult women (Anderson and Ray, 2015; Miguel, 2005; Oppong, 2006; Sossou, 2002). The cotton revolution in the fourteenth century greatly improved the prospect of widows. Ming and Qing China witnessed an unprecedented number of widows who participated in a wide range of economic and social activities. The precondition to widows’ participation in economic and social activities is survival. Stable incomes derived from textile production played a conducive role in widows’ survival. Relying on those incomes, widows not only survived, but had the financial latitude to support their children and in-laws (Zurndorfer, 1998; Sommer, 2000; Elvin, 1984). Another aspect of textile incomes was economic independence. A strong financial position critically shaped a widow’s status in the family of her deceased husband’s, and sometimes, in her natal family. Between 1300 and 1850, the improvement of widow well-being, which was closely related to cotton production, contributed to the broadening of women’s space in society. (Pomeranz, 2004; Bray, 1997; Pomeranz, 2005; Zhao, 2015). Data on the number of widows and their mortality in historical times are hard to come by. But the records counties and prefectures kept on “virtuous women”—a state-sponsored historical institution to commemorate widows with high morals—can be illuminating on the topic of widow survival. In the spirit of Song-Ming Neo-Confucianism, women were praised for maintaining 28 female chastity after their husband’s death. Those women were called “virtuous” women and often documented in local gazetteers for their glorified deeds. Before 1300, among all “virtuous” women, half of the women were “chaste windows” who provided for her in-laws and children for an number of decades, the other half were “heroic widows” who committed suicide upon their husband’s death to demonstrate their exemplary character (Jiazun, 1979). After 1300, cotton textiles began to financially empower women. The percentage of women who chose chaste widowhood over suicide likely increased. I hypothesize that cotton textiles tilted women’s decision towards chaste widowhood from suicide, as availability of financial means was key to widow survival.44 All else equal, women with no financial means would be at a higher risk to commit suicide. To test the relationship between cotton textile production and widow suicide, I search local gazetteers for records on “virtuous” women. To circumvent the problem of varying local standards of awarding “virtuous women” status, I focus on women awarded imperial testimonials of merit (jingbiao) by the central government. To have a sense of the timing of transition—from when cotton textiles began to positively shape women’s life trajectories—I start with records of jingbiao from the Ming Dynasty (1368-1644). Because I perform the search on prefecture-level gazetteers available on zhongguo fangzhi ku (China’s Gazetteer Database), Series I, I restrict the sample to prefectures that had at least one prefecture-level gazetteer from the Ming Dynasty available in the database. Based on the above criteria, a total of 89 prefectures are included in the sample. Table 6 shows that 41 out of 89 prefectures have pre-modern textile production. Table 6: jingbiao: Summary Statistics Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min. Widow suicide 0.438 1.588 0 Chase widowhood 1.815 4.617 0 jingbiao 2.253 5.411 0 Pre-modern textiles 0.466 0.461 0 Pre-modern textiles, binary 0.461 0.501 0 Latitude 30.395 4.73 19.193 Longitude 115.129 4.331 104.048 Max. 10 34 38 1 1 40.015 121.409 N 89 89 89 89 89 89 89 These numbers supply qualitative evidence that suggests that pre-modern textile production decreased the share of “virtuous” women committing suicide. In other words, women in regions where cotton textile production was more important had a greater chance of survival, holding constant their “virtuous women” status. In Column 3, A one-standard-deviation increase in 44 To be awarded “chase widow” status, a long wait is required. According to Qing regulations, to be eligible to the title of “ chase widow”, a woman either had to remain widowed since before the age of 30 years old to the age of 50 years old, or had been widowed for ten years or more but died before reaching 50 (Mann, 1987). The long time frame required to be eligible to the “chase widow” status heightened the importance of having financial resources at one’s disposal. Here I do not try to argue that having financial means was the single key factor in widows’ decision making; I acknowledge that many factors could be at play (Theiss, 2005; Ropp et al., 2001). 29 pre-modern textile production is associated with a decrease of 0.16 (0.32*0.51) search records on widow suicide, or 37% of the mean of widow suicide records. Cotton textiles enabled women to maintain a livelihood in the absence of their husband. From the perspective of parents, a daughter’s ability to support herself under adverse circumstances reduces their mental and financial exposure in a world characterized by uncertainty.45 I argue that the image of a financially empowered, capable and dependable unmarried adult woman, can lead to a notion that women can be productive and independent members of society. B Gender Norms and Female Labor Force Participation: Evidence from the Early Twentieth Century From 1840 onwards, China began to industrialize at a slow pace. Manufacturing jobs emerged and they typically required workers to work outside home. Conservative gender norms and concern for “purity” of women would predict few women would take manufacturing jobs. In reality, female labor force participation was extremely uneven across regions.The presence of women in industrial plants was much more common in Jiangsu, Zhejiang and Shanghai, where women even outnumbered men. Women working outside the home was extremely rare in Zhili, Shanxi and Shaanxi. Would pre-modern textiles influence women’s decision to participate in the labor force? Ideally, I would like having disaggregated data at the very onset of industrialization to examine how women’s initial responses to industrial job opportunities differed. Unfortunately, a still largely pre-modern and agrarian Chinese state at the time, did not possess the capacity to collect detailed labor statistics. One of the earliest censuses available that can help answer this question is the 1916 Economic Census. The census documents number of male and female workers working in a factory by province and industry, excluding household production workers. Table ?? provides summary statistics. As seen in the table, in an average province-industry pair, roughly 19% of the total workers were female, but with high variance. Table 7: Summary Statistics: Share of Female Workers in 1916 Variable Pre-modern textiles %Female #workers Log(#workers+1) Mean Std. Dev. 0.464 0.33 0.189 0.252 3839.652 11057.267 6.506 2.015 Min. Max. N 0.007 0.921 181 0 1 181 7 123127 181 2.079 11.721 181 To investigate the role of pre-modern textile production in female labor force participation, I regress share of female workers on pre-modern textiles. Table 8 suggests that in provinces with a higher percentage of population exposed to pre-modern textiles, a large share of women worked in factories. A few possible explanations are (a.) Persistence in specific skills. Women 45 Bossler (2000) finds evidence for a continued relationship between a married woman and her natal family. While a woman became a member of her husband’s extended family upon marriage, her natal family could still be involved in times of crisis. This includes cases in which a widowed woman in poverty imposed a financial burden on her natal family. 30 Table 8: 1916 Economic Census: Pre-modern Textile and Share of Female Workers (1) Pre-modern textiles Share of Female Workers (2) (3) 0.156∗∗∗ (0.0525) 0.124∗∗∗ (0.0450) No Yes 0.0844∗ (0.0448) 0.0445∗∗∗ (0.0134) Yes 181 0.0362 181 0.266 181 0.338 Log(#workers+1) Industry dummies Observations Adjusted R2 Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 Notes:The table reports the impact of pre-modern textiles on share of female workers in the early 20th century. The unit of observation is an industry within a province. The dependent variable is share of female workers. #workers referes to the total number of workers in an industry within a province. Robust standard errors are used in all specifications. who understood household production of textiles had an advantage in industrial production of textiles. (b.) Persistence in physical mobility. Pre-modern textiles provided women with opportunities to engage in market exchange. Women likely enjoyed a higher level of physical mobility than their counterparts in other places. (c) Persistence in the role of bread-winning females. Families used to incomes generated by women had to adapt to new economic realities that manufacturing jobs were better jobs for women to support a family. I rule out (a.) being the only explanation by showing that a larger share of female workers was found not only in textile manufacturing plants, but also in other industries. In fact, pre-modern textile production is positively correlated with the share of female workers in most industries, except for fur making. Figure 4 illustrates this point with a scatter plot and a fitted regression line for each of cotton textile manufacturing, knitting, dyeing, and match manufacturing. To further distinguish between (b.) and (c.) I would need higher quality data. Either (b.) or (c.) would be consistent with the hypothesis that pre-modern textile production generated gender norms in favor of women and influenced a range of later outcomes through the channel of reformed gender norms. These results could suggest an alternative mechanism for pre-modern textile production to affect modern-day outcomes: places that had more equal gender norms may have had more rapid industrialization aided by abundant female labor.46 Once the economy began to industrialize, growth and development can become proximate causes of better relative outcomes for women. To deal with, in the next section, I explicitly control for early industrialization as well as investigate its impact on the persistent effects of pre-modern textiles. 46 Previous studies have shown the effect of proto-industry on the locations of modern industries (Farnie, 1979) 31 Figure 4: Share of Female Workers in 1916 C The Persistence of Gender Norms after 1840 C.1 Resilience to Large Political and Economic Shocks Early Industrialization I try to address potentially uneven effects of the industrialization and modernization processes across counties. China began to industrialize from the 19th century onwards, first in treaty ports. Jia (2014) shows that treaty ports had a long-lasting impact on local economies. This is a potential source of bias if pre-modern textile locations overlapped with areas that experienced early industrialization, as gender norms might be affected by such drastic economic and social change. Historical evidence suggests that this should not be a major concern as industrialization in China was extremely limited and highly isolated (Fairbank, 1978).47 Column 1 and 2 of Table 9 shows coefficient estimates of textile production are robust to controlling for or omitting treaty ports. Treaty port status has an independent effect on reducing sex ratio imbalances. The interaction term between treaty port and pre-modern textiles is close to zero and insignificant, suggesting pre-modern textile production has no differential impact on modern sex ratio imbalances by treaty port status. The coefficient size of pre-modern textiles increases slightly when all treaty ports are excluded in Column 2. 47 During the late Qing and Republican China era, much of the rural and hinterland China continued to perform household production and their traditional lifestyles. 32 Missionary Influence Missionaries came to China to spread Christian religions in the 19th Century. They built churches, schools and hospitals. While only a small percentage of Chinese populations were converted, some of them might have had a disproportional influence on the rest of society. Since Christianity emphasizes the value of life, and specifies different gender norms from traditional Chinese religions, missionary activities might have changed local gender norms. To check this, I first include logged number of communicants per 10,000 plus 1 in the regression in Column 5. As expected, the percentage of believers in the population is positively correlated with a more normal sex ratio. The coefficient size of pre-modern textiles increases by roughly one-fifth, suggesting some of the effects of pre-modern textile production might have been previously masked by missionary activities in counties with no history of cotton textiles. I then include both logged number of believers per 10,000 plus 1 and its interaction with pre-modern textiles in Column 6. The positive sign of the interaction term hints at the possibility that the effect of pre-modern textile production is less persistent where the percentage of believers is high, but its coefficient is insignificant. 33 34 ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ 1038 0.305 Yes Yes Yes -0.886 (0.553) 0.128 (2.755) -3.748∗∗ (1.600) -3.300 (3.298) p < 0.01 1038 0.306 Yes Yes Yes -1.333∗∗ (0.586) 1.143 (0.996) 0.151 (2.705) -5.583∗∗ (1.897) -3.536 (3.091) (3) (4) Missionary influence 1535 0.310 Yes Yes Yes -0.473 (1.721) 2.031 (2.643) -3.743∗∗ (1.716) -5.129 (3.154) 1379 0.307 Yes Yes Yes -3.513∗ (1.832) -5.580 (3.330) 1535 0.312 -4.097 (2.436) 4.330∗ (2.187) Yes Yes Yes 0.833 (1.901) -4.207∗∗ (1.723) -5.087 (3.036) 1308 0.301 Yes Yes Yes 0.401 (1.909) -4.704∗∗ (1.758) -8.428∗∗ (3.245) (7) (8) Economic reforms 1038 0.306 -6.123∗∗∗ (1.876) -3.378 (2.252) -0.406 (4.390) -2.107 (3.025) 3.679 (4.400) -1.330∗∗ (0.577) 0.982 (0.938) -4.364 (2.992) 4.264 (3.495) Yes Yes Yes (9) All shocks 1038 0.303 Yes Yes Yes 0.0645 (2.731) -3.842∗∗ (1.623) -3.613 (3.389) (10) No shock Notes: The table reports the impact of intermediate shocks on sex ratio imbalances as well as on the persistent effects of pre-modern textiles. The unit of observation is a county in 2000 Census. The dependent variable is sex ratio at birth. Baseline controls are those used in Column 4 of baseresults. Christianity is measured by log (communicants per 10,000+1). “on the coast” refers to a county within 50 kilometers of the coast. Column 2 drops all treaty ports. Column 6 drops all provincial capitals. Column 8 drops all coastal counties. Column 9 include all interaction terms. Column 10 includes only baseline controls and uses the same sample as Column 9. As part of the baseline controls, treaty port status and provincial capital are controlled for in all specifications. Robust standard errors are clustered at the province level. p < 0.10, ∗ Standard errors in parentheses 1346 0.331 1535 0.310 Observations Adjusted R2 Yes Yes Yes -0.725 (1.682) -3.779∗∗ (1.519) Yes Yes Yes -3.517∗∗ (1.621) -4.796∗∗∗ (1.443) -0.371 (4.590) 0.785 (2.113) Pre-modern textiles × On the coast Baseline controls Region FE Province FE Pre-modern textiles × Christianity On the coast Pre-modern textiles × Provincial capital Christianity) Pre-modern textiles × Treaty port Provincial capital Treaty port Pre-modern textiles (2) Early industrialization (1) Sex ratio at birth (5) (6) State socialism Table 9: Persistence since 1840: Intermediate Shocks Post-1949 State Socialism China has been promoting gender equality through laws, policies and institutions for over half a century (Johnson, 2009). As gender equality has an important role in the communist ideal, China passed the marriage law in 1950 to grant women the right to free marriage and divorce, inherit property, and control of their children. The role of Chinese women changed from a “family private person” of traditional society to a “social person”, and Chinese women gained the same legal status as men. The Constitution of the People’s Republic of China enacted in 1954 expressly stated that women and men enjoy equal rights. China also mandated equal entry to the labor market and instituted equal pay for equal work for men and women (Entwisle and Henderson, 2000; Hannum and Xie, 1994; Johnson, 2009; Yang, 1999), and those equalization policies worked relatively well during the planned economy era. Despite uneven economic growth, contemporary China has kept most formal institutions that guarantee gender equality. Post-1949 socialist policies have undoubtedly shrunk the absolute size of gender gap and transformed gender norms to a large extent. However, it is less clear why post-1949 socialist polices should be more intense in places with pre-modern textile production. There is little local variation in formal institutions of China because of its high degree of political centralization.48 A potential source of variation in the enforcement of socialist policies is whether a county is in a provincial capital. If this is true, the effects of pre-modern textiles could be less persistent in provincial capitals where political shocks were larger. I drop provincial capitals in Column 4 and find the coefficient stays almost the same. In column 3, I include the interaction term between pre-modern textiles and provincial capital and find it to be slightly positive but not significant. Recent Economic Reforms In the midst of post-1979 economic reforms, the state has relaxed part of its control on the economy and society. Previously hidden gender inequality has since surfaced (Li and Lavely, 2003). On one hand, there remains very little variation in either labor laws or maternity leave law at a local level. On the other hand, the recent thirty years of growth in China could have led some regions to develop temporary rules or measures that increase or decrease gender equality as a byproduct of economic growth. I am not overly concerned with recent manifestations of already existing gender bias, as this could just be endogenous to pre-modern textiles. To address the effect of heterogeneous economic growth and economic institutions in recent years, I control for per capita income in county-level regressions (Column 1 and 2 of Table 2), along with other contemporary controls. To see if economic reforms are associated with differential persistent effects of pre-modern textiles, I interact coastal counties with pre-modern textiles in Column 7.49 I find that large economic shocks appearing in the coast area might indeed weaken the effect of pre-modern textiles. Yet, the insignificant 48 Urban authorities in China have little or no ability to shape labors laws and policies at a local level. Rural China does have more policies generated through democratic processes at the local level (O’brien and Li, 2000). 49 China’s export-led economy in the past 30 years has rendered coastal regions a tremendous growth advantage. Yangtze Delta and Pearl River Delta are home to million of exporters.On the side of policy interventions, the central government created the earliest special economic zones all on the coast too. 35 coefficient means that no reliable interpretation can be inferred from these results.50 In Column 8 I simply drop all coastal regions, and find the coefficient size of interest increases by roughly a third. This suggests that pre-modern textile production has a larger effect of reducing sex ratio imbalances in the non-coastal region than in the coastal region. I include controls for large political and economic shocks and interacted them with pre-modern textiles in Column 9. This results in a sample of 1038 counties. I find pre-modern textiles reduces sex ratio imbalances by 6.1 boys per hundred girls in places with no exposure to any of the large political and economic shocks, when those shocks are taken as exogenous. Within the same sample, in Column 10, pre-modern textile production reduces sex ratio imbalanced by 3.8 boys per hundred girls. The analysis of those shocks suggests that the persistent effects of pre-modern textile production are highly resilient. D Gender-Role Attitudes and Son Preference in Contemporary China: Evidence from CGSS Thus far I have reviewed the history of pre-modern textile production advancing women’s position and shaping gender norms, and examined a number of outcomes closely related to gender norms but not studied gender attitudes themselves. Now I directly turn to direct evidence on gender norms. CGSS 2010 (Chinese General Social Surveys) provides an unprecedented opportunity to examine gender-role attitudes among the Chinese. The survey contains questions regarding beliefs and attitudes associated with women. In addition, the CGSS includes information on age group, gender, urban/rural site, marital status, education attainment, party member status and household registration status. The first measure of beliefs about women is constructed from each respondent’s view of the following question: “Do you agree with the following statement: men are naturally more capable than women?” The second measure comes from the question: “Do you agree with the following statement: men should focus on career; women should focus on family?” The respondent can choose from a scale of 1 to 5 ranging from “completely disagree” to “completely agree”. In addition, I create a measure from two questions on the subjective assessment of how many sons and daughters one wants to have. For those who answer they want more sons than daughters, son preference takes on the value of 1. For those who are indifferent between sons and daughters, or want the same number of sons and daughters, or want more daughters than sons, son preference takes on the value of 0. I take a subsample of CGSS to match the geographic coverage of the main sample used in Section IV. Summary statistics are available in Table A.6. 50 Besides, heterogeneity in the treatment itself can not ruled out as an alternative interpretation here. While emperors between 1300 and 1850 banned ocean trade periodically between 1300 and 1850, the treatment of pre-modern textiles differ in magnitude and intensity for coastal regions. 36 37 ∗ Standard errors in parentheses ∗∗ p < 0.05, 5585 0.093 ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 5578 0.098 -0.190∗∗∗ (0.0677) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 5594 0.035 -0.0883 (0.0734) No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes 5591 0.109 -0.125∗ (0.0675) Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes 5584 0.116 -0.117∗ (0.0664) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 5533 0.042 0.034 -0.321∗ (0.184) Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes 5535 -0.307∗ (0.176) No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes 0.045 5525 -0.324∗ (0.185) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Son preference (7) (8) (9) Logit Notes: The table reports the impact of pre-modern textiles on gender-role attitudes and son preference. The unit of observation is a survey respondent in CGSS 2010 (Chinese General Social Surveys). Contemporary, historical and geographic controls are the same as in Table 2. Robust standard errors are clustered at the county level. p < 0.10, 5587 0.017 Observations Adjusted R2 Pseudo R2 Pre-modern textiles -0.169∗∗ -0.199∗∗∗ (0.0663) (0.0646) Age group No Yes Female No Yes Education No Yes Female ×Education No Yes Individual controls No No Contemporary controls Yes Yes Historical controls Yes Yes Geographic controls Yes Yes Region FE Yes Yes Men naturally more capable Women focus on family (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) OLS Table 10: Gender-role Attitudes and Son Preference in Contemporary China: Evidence from CGSS I regress pre-modern textile production on beliefs about women and son preference with the same controls used in Column 1 and 2 Table 2 as well as in Table 5. Robust standard errors are clustered at the county level for all specifications. Table 10 summarizes the results. Column 1 through 6 report OLS results for beliefs about women. Column 7 through 9 focus on son preference. Columns 1, 4, 7 contain no individual controls; Columns 2, 5, 8 include basic individual controls such as age group, gender and education attainment; Columns 3, 5, 9 contain a full set of individual controls. Individuals in counties with pre-modern textile production are more likely to disagree with the statement that men are naturally more capable, or the statement that women should focus on family, and less likely to favor sons over daughters. Pre-modern textile production is systematically correlated with more progressive gender norms and weaker son preference. VII Conclusion Women’s productivity in textile production varied from society to society historically, and it often depended on the technology and local geo-climatic conditions. Anthropologists posit that the shift from flax to wool in the ancient Middle East led to a decline in the status of women as linen was cultivated on a small scale by women and children while wool production relied on male management of sheep herds (McCorriston, 1997). In historical China, the switch from linen to cotton empowered women (Bray, 1997). This paper provides evidence that a portion of the variation in gender norms and gender inequality in modern day China can be accounted for by pre-modern textile production. It suggests that gender norms can be shaped by large and long-lasting relative productivity shocks. I use both OLS and IV to estimate the impact of pre-modern textile production on today’s sex ratio imbalances. The results are robust to the exclusion of Yangtze Delta, a region famous for pre-modern textile production and a number of features associated with a highly developed historical economy. I also extend my analysis to include other variables more commonly discussed in the context of gender equality, such as literacy and education. My finding from county-level regressions cannot be explained by past tea or rice production, commerce prior to the period of cotton textile production, state presence, current textile industry, or modernization hypothesis. My micro-level analysis lends support to my county-level analysis, and generates additional insights into how gender bias worked itself into economic and social outcomes during the planned economy era. I find that pre-modern textile production helps to explain women’s position even in the socialist period of China. In both 1982 and 1990 census, pre-modern textile production is positively associated with share of women with political or managerial positions and wife heading the household. In addition to analyzing gender norms in contemporary China, I also look at the impact of pre-modern textiles on the gender norms and gender equality in the past. I find evidence 38 for an adaptation in gender norms to the cotton revolution at latest by the end of the Ming Dynasty (1366-1644). Pre-modern textile production likely reduced the rate of widow suicide and increased quality of life, self-esteem and social status of widows at the time. Based on the fact that widows, compared to married women, were more poised to making independent decisions and as well as being visible in public space, I conclude the elevated status of widows might have contributed to a more positive evaluation of women’s ability and their role in society. Another historical period I examine is the onset of industrialization in modern China. I find premodern textile production is positively associated with share of female workers in manufacturing jobs. I interpret this as a reflection of more relaxed gender norms in places with pre-modern textile production that allowed more women to work outside home to take advantage of new economic opportunities. I examine a number of large political and economic shocks and their impact on the transmission of gender norms since China began to modernize in 1850. After acknowledging the role each of those shocks in gender bias reflected in sex ratio imbalances, I find coefficients of pre-modern textile production remain significant and similar in magnitude to baseline estimates. The persistence effects of pre-modern textiles are overall highly resilient; coefficients of pre-modern textiles interacted with those shocks do provide suggestive evidence that those intermediate shocks might have served to temporarily or permanently weaken the persistence effects of pre-modern textiles on gender norms. Had there been none of those shocks, pre-modern textile production might have reduced sex ratio imbalances by six boys per hundred girls rather than five boys per hundred girls. Finally, I investigate gender-role attitudes Chinese people hold in contemporary China, and I find pre-modern textile production is systematically correlated with more progressive gender norms and weaker son preference. 39 References Afeng (2002). Huizhou wenshu suo jian mingqing shidai funv de diwei yu quanli(Status of Women in Ming and Qing China from Huizhou Archives). Ph. D. thesis. Alesina, A., P. Giuliano, and N. Nunn (2013). On the origins of gender roles: Women and the plough. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128 (2), 469–530. Allen, R. C. (2009). Agricultural productivity and rural incomes in England and the Yangtze delta, c.1620ñc.1820. Economic History Review 62 (3), 525–550. Allen, R. C., J.-P. Bassino, D. Ma, C. Moll-Murata, and J. L. Van Zanden (2011). Wages, prices, and living standards in China, 1738–1925: in comparison with Europe, Japan, and India. The Economic History Review 64 (s1), 8–38. Almond, D., H. Li, and S. Zhang (2013, June). Land reform and sex selection in China. Working Paper 19153, National Bureau of Economic Research. Anderson, S. and M. Eswaran (2009). What determines female autonomy? evidence from Bangladesh. Journal of Development Economics 90 (2), 179–191. Anderson, S. and D. Ray (2015). Missing unmarried women. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. Ashraf, N., D. Karlan, and W. Yin (2010). Female empowerment: Impact of a commitment savings product in the Philippines. World development 38 (3), 333–344. Barber, E. J. (1991). Prehistoric textiles. The development of cloth in the Neolithic and Bronze Ages with special reference to the Aegean, 223–243. Bertocchi, G. and M. Bozzano (2013). Women, medieval commerce, and the education gender gap. Bertrand, M., E. Kamenica, and J. Pan (2015). Gender identity and relative income within households. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, qjv001. Bisin, A., E. Patacchini, T. Verdier, and Y. Zenou (2011, May). Formation and persistence of oppositional identities. CEPR Discussion Papers 8380, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers. Bisin, A. and T. Verdier (2001, April). The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. Journal of Economic Theory 97 (2), 298–319. Bossler, B. J. (2000). ” a daughter is a daughter all her life”: Affinal relations and women’s networks in song and late imperial China. Late Imperial China 21 (1), 77–106. Bray, F. (1997). Technology and gender: Fabrics of power in late imperial China. University of California Pr. Burda, M., D. S. Hamermesh, and P. Weil (2007, March). Total Work, Gender and Social Norms. NBER Working Papers 13000, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Chen, J., S. Wu, Y. Zhou, and X. Qian (1991). Songjiang qu ge (Poetry of Songjiang). Zhong hua shu ju. Chen, Y., H. Li, and L. Meng (2013). Prenatal sex selection and missing girls in china: Evidence from the diffusion of diagnostic ultrasound. Journal of Human Resources 48 (1), 36–70. Chow, R. (1991). Woman and Chinese modernity: The politics of reading between West and East. U of Minnesota Press. Chung, W. and M. D. Gupta (2007). The decline of son preference in South Korea: The roles of development and public policy. Population and Development Review 33 (4), 757–783. Daul, G. B. and E. Moretti (2008, Oct). The demand for sons. Review of Economic Studies 75 (4), 10851120. De Moor, T. and J. L. Van Zanden (2010). Girl power: the European marriage pattern and labour markets in the North Sea region in the late medieval and early modern period. The Economic History Review 63 (1), 1–33. Deininger, K., A. Goyal, and H. Nagarajan (2010). Inheritance law reform and women’s access to capital: evidence from india’s hindu succession act. Ebenstein, A. (2010). The “missing girls” of China and the unintended consequences of the one child policy. Journal of Human Resources 45 (1), 87–115. 40 Ebrey, P. (1990). Women, marriage, and the family in chinese history. Heritage of China, 197–223. Edlund, L. (1999). Son preference, sex ratios, and marriage patterns. Journal of Political Economy 107 (6), 1275–1304. Elvin, M. (1984). Female virtue and the state in China. Past and Present, 111–152. Entwisle, B. and G. Henderson (2000). Re-drawing boundaries: work, households, and gender in China, Volume 25. Univ of California Press. Fairbank, J. K. (1978). The Cambridge History of China: Late Ching, 1800-1911, pt. 2. Cambridge University Press. Farnie, D. (1979). The English Cotton Industry and the World Market: 1815-1896. Oxford University Press. Fernández, R. (2007). Alfred marshall lecture women, work, and culture. Journal of the European Economic Association 5 (2-3), 305–332. Fernández, R. and A. Fogli (2009). Culture: An empirical investigation of beliefs, work, and fertility. American Economic Journal. Macroeconomics 1 (1), 146. Flynn, D. O. and A. Giráldez (1995). Born with a” silver spoon”: The origin of world trade in 1571. Journal of World History, 201–221. Fortin, N. M. (2005). Gender role attitudes and the labour-market outcomes of women across OECD countries. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 21 (3), 416–438. Goldin, C. and T. Schultz (1995). The u-shaped female labor force function in economic development and economic history. Investment in Womens Human Capital and Economic Development. Goldstone, J. A. (1996). Gender, work, and culture: Why the industrial revolution came early to England but late to China. Sociological Perspectives 39 (1), 1–21. Greif, A. and G. Tabellini (2010). Cultural and institutional bifurcation: China and europe compared. The American economic review , 135–140. Greif, A. and G. Tabellini (2015). The Clan and the City: Sustaining Cooperation in China and Europe. Working Paper 445, IGIER (Innocenzo Gasparini Institute for Economic Research). Grosjean, P. (2011, December). A History of Violence: The Culture of Honor as a Determinant of Homicide in the US South. Discussion Papers 2011-13, School of Economics, The University of New South Wales. Grosjean, P. and R. Khattar (2014). It’s raining men! hallelujah? Gu, Y. (1995). Zhao yu zhi:Jiangnan, Volume 9 (reprint ed.). Xu xiu si ku quan shu. Guiso, L., P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales (2006). Does culture affect economic outcomes? The Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 (2), 23–48. Gupta, B. (2014, Feb). Where have all the brides gone? son preference and marriage in India over the twentieth century. The Economic History Review 67 (1), 1–24. Hannum, E. and Y. Xie (1994). Trends in educational gender inequality in China: 1949-1985. University of Michigan. Hansen, C., P. Jensen, and C. Skovsgaard (2015). Modern gender roles and agricultural history: the neolithic inheritance. Journal of Economic Growth, 1–40. Harrell, S. (1995). Chinese historical microdemography, Volume 20. Univ of California Press. Hu, L. and A. Schlosser (2015). Prenatal sex selection and girls well-being: Evidence from india. The Economic Journal . Huang, P. C. C. (1990). The peasant family and rural development in the Yangzi Delta, 1350-1988. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Huang, R. (1964a). The Grand Canal During the Ming Dynasty: 1368-1644. University Microfilms. Huang, R. (1964b). The Grand Canal During the Ming Dynasty: 1368-1644. University Microfilms. Jayachandran, S. (2015). The roots of gender inequality in developing countries. Annual Review of Economics. Jha, S. (2013). Trade, institutions, and ethnic tolerance: Evidence from South Asia. American Political Science Review 107 (04), 806–832. Jia, R. (2014). The legacies of forced freedom: China’s treaty ports. Review of Economics and Statistics. forthcoming. 41 Jiazun, D. (1979). A Statistical Analysis of Virtuous Women by Dynasty. Ph. D. thesis. Johnson, K. A. (2009). Women, the family, and peasant revolution in China. University of Chicago Press. Kang, C. (1977). The development of cotton textile production in China. Harvard East Asian Monographs 74. Lee, J. Z. and C. D. Campbell (2007). Fate and Fortune in Rural China: Social Organization and Population Behavior in Liaoning 1774-1873, Volume 31. Cambridge University Press. Li, B. (1997). ”men farms and women weaves” and the formation of the role of ”half the sky” of women in peasant family economy: a study of women’s work in jiangnan during the ming-qing times. Researches in Chinese Economic History 3, 001. Li, B. and P.-C. Li (1998). Agricultural development in Jiangnan, 1620-1850. Macmillan. Li, J. and W. Lavely (2003). Village context, women’s status, and son preference among rural Chinese women. Rural Sociology 68 (1), 87–106. Lin, M.-J., J.-T. Liu, and N. Qian (2014). More missing women, fewer dying girls: The impact of sexselective abortion on sex at birth and relative female mortality in taiwan. Journal of the European Economic Association 12 (4), 899–926. Ma, D. (2005). Textiles in the Pacific, 1500-1900. Ashgate/Variorum. Man, C. O. (2011). Socioeconomic history of the Ming and Qing Dynasty from a gender perspective: the histories of agriculture, textile, commerce, and consumers. Journal of Chinese Studies 52 (01), 95—127. Mann, S. (1987). Widows in the kinship, class, and community structures of Qing dynasty China. Journal of Asian Studies 46 (1), 37–56. Mann, S. (1997). Precious records: Women in China’s long eighteenth century. Stanford University Press. McCorriston, J. (1997). Textile extensification, alienation, and social stratification in ancient mesopotamia. Current Anthropology 38 (4), 517–535. Miguel, E. (2005, October). Poverty and witch killing. Review of Economic Studies 72 (4), 1153–1172. Moen, P., M. A. Erickson, and D. Dempster-McClain (1997). Their mother’s daughters? the intergenerational transmission of gender attitudes in a world of changing roles. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 281–293. Nunn, N. (2012). Culture and the historical process. Economic History of Developing Regions 27 (sup1), S108–S126. Nunn, N. and L. Wantchekon (2011, December). The Slave Trade and the Origins of Mistrust in Africa. American Economic Review 101 (7), 3221–52. O’brien, K. J. and L. Li (2000). Accommodating “democracy” in a one-party state: Introducing village elections in China. The China Quarterly 162, 465–489. Oppong, C. (2006). Familial roles and social transformations older men and women in sub-saharan africa. Research on Aging 28 (6), 654–668. Oster, E. (2005). Hepatitis b and the case of the missing women. Journal of Political Economy 113 (6), 1163–1216. Pomeranz, K. (2002). Beyond the East-West binary: Resituating development paths in the eighteenthcentury world. The Journal of Asian Studies 61 (02), 539–590. Pomeranz, K. (2004). Women’s work, family, and economic development in Europe and East Asia: long-term trajectories and contemporary comparisons. In G. Arrighi, T. Hamashita, and M. Selden (Eds.), The resurgence of East Asia: 500, 150 and 50 year perspectives. Routledge. Pomeranz, K. (2005). Women’s work and the economics of respectability. In B. Goodman and W. Larson (Eds.), Gender in Motion: Divisons of Labor and Cultural Change in Late Imperial and Modern China, pp. 239–63. Pomeranz, K. (2009). The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy. Princeton University Press. Qian, N. (2008, August). Missing women and the price of tea in China: The effect of sex-specific earnings on sex imbalance. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (3), 1251–1285. 42 Ropp, P. S. (1994). Women in late imperial china: a review of recent english-language scholarship [1]. Women’s History Review 3 (3), 347–383. Ropp, P. S., P. Zamperini, and H. T. Zurndorfer (2001). Passionate women: Female suicide in late imperial China. Brill. Shiue, C. H. and W. Keller (2007, September). Markets in China and Europe on the eve of the industrial revolution. American Economic Review 97 (4), 1189–1216. Skinner, G.W., H. M. and M. L. Berman. Socioeconomic macroregions of China. http://hdl.handle.net/1902.1/21766, Harvard Dataverse, V1 . Sommer, M. H. (2000). Sex, law, and society in late imperial China. Stanford University Press. Sossou, M.-A. (2002). Widowhood practices in west africa: the silent victims. International Journal of Social Welfare 11 (3), 201–209. (1909). Textile World Record. Number v. 37. Lord & Nagle Company. Theiss, J. M. (2005). Disgraceful matters: The politics of chastity in eighteenth-century China. Univ of California Press. Vella, F. and L. Farré (2007, October). The Intergenerational Transmission Of Gender Role Attitudes And Its Implications For Female Labor Force Participation. Working Papers. Serie AD 2007-23, Instituto Valenciano de Investigaciones Económicas, S.A. (Ivie). Voigtländer, N. and H.-J. Voth (2012). Persecution perpetuated: The medieval origins of Anti-Semitic Violence in Nazi Germany. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (3), 1339–1392. Voigtländer, N. and H.-J. Voth (2013). How the west” invented” fertility restriction. American Economic Review 103 (6), 2227–64. Watson, R. S. and P. B. Ebrey (1991). Marriage and inequality in Chinese society, Volume 12. Univ of California Press. Wei, S.-J. and X. Zhang (2011). The competitive saving motive: Evidence from rising sex ratios and savings rates in China. Journal of Political Economy 119 (3), 511 – 564. Wong, R. B. c. m. (2002). The search for european differences and domination in the early modern world: a view from Asia. The American Historical Review 107 (2), 447–469. Yang, M. M.-h. (1999). Spaces of their own: women’s public sphere in transnational China, Volume 4. U of Minnesota Press. Yang, Z., B. Huang, and c. Cheng (2006). Mingdai yizhan kao(Courier stations in the Ming Dynasty). Shanghai Ancient Books Publishing House. Zhao, c. (2015). Hidden modernity-social life and romantic experience of Ming and Qing women. Zhi shi chu ban she. Zurndorfer, H. T. (1998). Chinese women in the imperial past: new perspectives, Volume 44. Brill. 43 A Appendix Table A.1: Robustness Check: Subsamples Sex ratio at birth (1) (2) (3) (4) Yangtze Delta Net in-migration Pre-modern textiles Yangtze Delta -3.555∗ (1.686) -11.25∗ (6.252) -4.497∗∗ (1.703) -3.968∗∗ (1.726) -5.238∗ (2.779) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes -3.379∗∗∗ (0.926) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 1535 0.310 1361 0.311 1535 0.288 888 0.299 Net in migration Baseline controls Region FE Province FE Observations Adjusted R2 Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 Notes: See Table 2. Baseline controls are the same as in Column 4 of Table2. Yangtze Delta provinces are Jiangsu, Zhejiang & Shanghai. Column 1 directly controls for Yangtze Delta. Column 2 omits all yangtze Delta provinces. Column 3 directly controls for net in-migration. Column 4 omits all counties with positive net migration. Robust Standard errors are clustered at the province level. 44 Table A.2: Robustness: Sex Ratio at Birth after 1990 Sex ratio at birth (1) Aged 5 to 9 (2) Age 1 to 4 2000 (3) At birth -2.967∗∗ (1.295) Yes Yes Yes -5.085∗∗ (1.913) Yes Yes Yes -3.555∗ (1.686) Yes Yes Yes -3.132∗ (1.527) Yes Yes Yes -1.193 (1.610) Yes Yes Yes 1535 0.272 1535 0.364 1535 0.310 1461 0.385 1461 0.245 Pre-modern textiles Baseline controls Region FE Province FE Observations Adjusted R2 Standard errors in parentheses ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ (4) (5) Age 1 to 4 At birth 2010 p < 0.01 Notes:The table reports the impact of pre-modern textiles on sex ratio imbalances among young cohorts. The unit of observation is a county in the 2000 or 2010 Census. Baseline controls are the same as in Column 4 of baseresults. Column 4 and 5 only include counties with no administrative code change between 2000 and 2010. Robust standard errors are clustered at the province level. Table A.3: Robustness: Other Gender Outcomes (1) Pre-modern textiles Baseline controls Control for male outcomes Region FE Province FE (5) (6) Women’s Illiteracy 1990 0.167∗∗∗ (0.0488) Yes No Yes Yes 0.106∗∗ (0.0394) Yes Yes Yes Yes 0.163∗∗∗ (0.0522) Yes No Yes Yes 0.130∗∗∗ (0.0304) Yes Yes Yes Yes -0.0314∗∗ (0.0116) Yes No Yes Yes -0.0113 (0.00674) Yes Yes Yes Yes 1535 0.592 1535 0.932 1461 0.651 1461 0.946 1126 0.418 1126 0.783 Observations Adjusted R2 Standard errors in parentheses (2) (3) (4) Women’s years of education 2000 2010 ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 Notes:The table reports the impact of pre-modern textiles on women’s education and women’s illiteracy. The unit of observation is a county in the 2000, 2010 or 1990 Census. Baseline controls are the same as in Column 4 of baseresults. Column 2 and 4 control for men’s years of schooling. Column 6 controls for men’s illiteracy rate. Robust standard errors are clustered at the province level. 45 46 ∗∗ p < 0.05, 1503 0.318 Yes ∗∗∗ p < 0.01 1535 0.309 Yes 0.414 (0.825) -0.0463 (0.104) -3.562∗ (1.687) 1535 0.311 Yes -0.766∗ (0.363) -3.431∗ (1.673) Sex ratio at birth (3) (4) Pre-1300 State commerce presence 1535 0.228 -0.821 (0.473) Yes -2.919∗ (1.553) (5) Industrial persistence The table reports the results of testing competing hypotheses. The unit of observation is a county in 2000 Census. The dependent variable is sex ratio at birth. Baseline controls are those used in Column 4 of baseresults. Pre-1300 commerce is measured by log (commercial tax quota in 1077+1). #historical courier routes refers to number of courier routes passing a county historically. Robust standard errors are clustered at the province level. p < 0.10, 1503 0.317 Observations Adjusted R2 ∗ Yes Standard errors in parentheses (2) Tea -3.490∗ -3.394∗ (1.682) (1.722) 0.00531 (0.00510) 0.615∗ (0.307) Baseline controls #textile companies #historical courier routes Pre-1300 commerce2 Pre-1300 commerce Rice suitability Tea suitability Pre-modern textiles (1) Rice Table A.4: Competing Hypotheses Table A.5: Summary Statistics: 1990 Census Variable Pre-modern textiles Mean 0.446 Std. Dev. 0.444 Min. 0 Max. 1 N 140 Head Political or Managerial Position 0.560 0.017 0.496 0.13 0 0 1 1 2596827 3415654 0.101 0.085 0.083 0.102 0.111 0.093 0.075 0.079 0.058 0.043 0.04 0.038 0.031 0.025 0.017 0.01 0.007 0.302 0.279 0.276 0.302 0.314 0.291 0.264 0.27 0.233 0.204 0.196 0.191 0.174 0.156 0.13 0.101 0.085 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 0.449 0.501 0.004 0.046 0.497 0.5 0.062 0.21 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 0.802 0.006 0.192 0.399 0.077 0.394 0 0 0 1 1 1 4259043 4259043 4259043 0.804 0.982 0.191 4.476 0.873 0.397 0.134 0.491 1.869 0.333 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 5 20 1 5139572 5828835 5828835 5828835 5828835 Age— 0 to 4 5 to 9 10 to 14 15 to 19 20 to 24 25 to 29 30 to 34 35 to 39 40 to 44 45 to 49 50 to 54 55 to 59 60 to 64 65 to 69 70 to 74 75 to 79 80+ Marital status— Single/never married Married/in union Separated/divorced/spouse absent Widowed Employment status— Employed Unemployed Inactive Literate Han # own children under age 5 # own family member At least one married couple 47 Table A.6: Summary Statistics: CGSS Variable Pre-Modern Textiles Mean 0.554 Std. Dev. 0.5 Min. 0 Max. 1 N 74 “Men are naturally more capable” “Women should focus on family Son preference 2.982 3.62 0.684 1.265 1.226 0.465 1 1 0 5 5 1 6699 6706 6634 Han ethnicity Female Urban site Communist Age– Less than 20 21 to 30 31 to 40 41 to 50 51 to 60 61 to 70 71 to 80 81 to 90 90+ Marital status– Unmarried Cohabited Married Separated Divorced Widowed Educational attainment– Less than primary completed Primary completed Secondary completed University completed Household Registration– Registered as rural Registered as urban Registered as other 0.976 0.518 0.61 0.173 0.154 0.5 0.488 0.379 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 6705 6718 6718 6709 0.018 0.116 0.184 0.252 0.197 0.134 0.078 0.02 0.001 0.134 0.321 0.387 0.434 0.398 0.341 0.268 0.14 0.023 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 5498 5498 5498 5498 5498 5498 5498 5498 5498 0.081 0.002 0.815 0.004 0.015 0.083 0.272 0.045 0.389 0.065 0.121 0.277 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 5498 5498 5498 5498 5498 5498 0.162 0.012 0.539 0.174 0.368 0.109 0.498 0.379 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 5496 5496 5496 5496 0.613 0.335 0.052 0.487 0.472 0.222 0 0 0 1 1 1 5498 5498 5498 48