GERENCIA ACADÉMICA, GOBERNANZA Y ADMINISTRACIÓN DE
Transcription
GERENCIA ACADÉMICA, GOBERNANZA Y ADMINISTRACIÓN DE
GERENCIA ACADÉMICA, GOBERNANZA Y ADMINISTRACIÓN DE LA UPR La gerencia académica, gobernanza y administración de la Universidad de Puerto Rico sigue de cerca la organización y gerencia de las universidades de la mayoría del mundo. El organigrama gerencial administrativo de la UPR se encuentra en las Figuras 1a y 1b y es representativa de una multi-universidad con múltiples recintos, con misiones y metas diferenciadas. Como sistema complejo que contiene en su seno tres recintos graduados y de investigación y ocho recintos subgraduados, guarda en su organización alguna semejanza con el sistema publico de educación superior de California (Universidad de California y la Universidad del Estado de California, si se ven como un solo sistema) y el de SUNY del Estado de Nueva York. Pero un análisis más detallado de estos sistemas demuestra que la UPR como sistema es “apsque pares” (que no tiene par); por esta razón, la UPR hay que analizarla como un sistema único que necesita un sistema organizativo gerencial hecho para responder a sus necesidades particulares. El documento adjunto, titulado “Naturaleza y Funciones de la Junta Universitaria en el Contexto de la Organización de la UPR”, por Jorge A. Cruz Emeric, de septiembre del 2007, describe con un alto grado de precisión las funciones y responsabilidades de la gerencia académica: Presidente, Rectores, Decanos y Directores de Departamento que corresponde al ordenamiento jerárquico y vertical de la universidad en la toma de decisiones, distribución de recursos, mecanismos de rendir cuentas y flujo de datos e información sobre la operación de la institución como una corporación a la usanza de la tradición universitaria. También describe y establece las prerrogativas y responsabilidades de los siguientes cuerpos asesores y/o que toman decisiones, en los que participan los profesores y estudiantes que constituyen parte de la gobernanza de la universidad y que siguen la tradición académica, a saber: Junta de Síndicos, Junta Universitaria, Junta Administrativa, Senado Académico, Claustro de Facultad y Claustro de Departamento. Es vital entender estas complejas estructuras antes de analizar las fortalezas y debilidades de la estructura de Gerencia Académica, Gobernanza y Administración de la UPR. Para entender y evaluar la gerencia académica, gobernanza y administración de la UPR es esencial comprender que la organización de las universidades es una organización híbrida y compleja que consiste de dos partes que obedecen principios organizacionales, que para el que no está familiarizado con ellos, pueden parecerle antitéticos e incompatibles, pero que las grandes universidades han logrado hacerlo compatibles y armónicos (ver los siguientes dos artículos adjuntos a este escrito: “The Center: The Top American Research Universities” y “The Center: University Organization, Governance, and Competitiveness”, informes anuales de “The Lombardi Program on Measuring University Performance, 2001 y 2002”). La primera parte es el escalafón gerencial/ administrativo, el que popularmente se denomina “La Administración”, que emula la estructura corporativa americana, organizada en forma vertical y jerárquica con una clara cadena de mando. Ésta es responsable de obtener y distribuir los recursos que la universidad necesita para mantener la calidad y productividad de los profesores y estudiantes. La misma está compuesta por la gerencia académica que, en orden descendente de jerarquía, es: Presidente (del sistema), Rectores (de los Recintos que componen el sistema), Decanos y Directores de Departamento. La segunda parte de la gobernanza de la universidad 2 emana del concepto medieval de “la cofradías o gremios artesanales”, compuesto primordialmente por los profesores y, en algunos casos, puede incluir la participación de estudiantes con un ámbito limitado de participación. Estos gremios son primordialmente responsables por el contenido académico; el ámbito y la calidad de la investigación; la calidad y pertinencia de los grados académicos que confiere la institución; y por el reclutamiento, nombramiento, permanencia y ascenso de sus pares que en esencia controla la puerta de entrada a futuros miembros de la cofradía. Estos gremios son, por su propia naturaleza, autorregulados, como lo eran las cofradías y gremios medievales y, en última instancia, son responsables por la calidad, prestigio y productividad de la universidad; de ahí que la plantilla de profesores y la calidad del estudiantado son determinantes para el éxito de una universidad. La participación de los gremios de profesores en la gobernanza de la institución está contenida en las siguientes estructuras universitarias: Comités y Claustro Departamentales, Comités y Claustro de Facultad y Senados Académicos. En el caso de la UPR, esta participación también incluye la Junta Universitaria, estructura que es “apsque pares” cuando se compara con otros Sistemas de Multi-Universidades con Recintos geográficamente distribuidos. Cuando se aprobó la Ley de la UPR en el 1966, la UPR consistía de tres recintos con una matrícula total de 28,194 estudiantes, a saber: el Recinto de Río Piedras, con una matricula de 21,133 estudiantes, que ofrecía grados de bachillerato, grados profesionales, algunas maestrías y un programa de PhD en Estudios Hispánicos; el Recinto de Ciencias Médicas, con una matricula de 686, era fundamentalmente una Escuela de Medicina y Odontología con algunos otros grados profesionales y cuatro programas de PhD de reciente creación; el Recinto de Mayagüez, con una matrícula de 5,370, era el “Land Grant College” de Puerto Rico, con su actividad centrada en Agricultura e Ingeniería y algunos programas de Maestría; y un Colegio Regional en Humacao con una matricula de 1,005. En los 45 años que han trascurrido desde la aprobación de la Ley en el 1966, la Universidad se ha transformado en forma dramática en tamaño, complejidad de sus ofrecimientos, número y diferenciación de las misiones y metas de sus recintos, y del entorno y realidad de la Educación Superior en Puerto Rico. Así que no es sorprendente que las estructuras y reglas para la gerencia académica, gobernanza y administración no resulten apropiadas para los retos del Siglo 21. En el 1966, el Sistema de Educación Superior de Puerto Rico y la UPR para todo propósito práctico eran una y la misma cosa; la ley reconoció esa realidad al definir a la UPR “como órgano de la educación superior”. En la actualidad, ésta ya no es la realidad. La UPR como sistema público de educación superior solo educa uno de cada tres estudiantes del Sistema de Educación Superior de Puerto Rico, admite los estudiantes con los índices más altos en los exámenes de entrada a la Universidad y tiene el por ciento más alto de estudiantes que provienen de las escuelas privadas (60%), dejándole en forma creciente la responsabilidad de educar al mayor número de estudiantes de bajo ingreso al sector privado. El crecimiento del sector privado de Educación Superior despuntó con la llegada de los fondos de becas federales (BEOG y Pell Grants) al principio de la década de los ‘70. El 74% de los fondos operacionales de las instituciones privadas de Educación Superior proviene de fuentes federales; de esta manera, los fondos federales están financiando un importante y creciente sector de la Educación Superior en Puerto Rico. Simultáneamente, con este crecimiento del sector 3 privado, la UPR incrementó el número de Recintos de 4 en el 1966 a 11; y desarrolló sus programas doctorales, particularmente en las disciplinas de Ciencia y Tecnología (C&T) de 6 en el 1996 a 32. Además, la actividad de I+D e Innovación despuntó después del 1986 cuando el sistema de la UPR obtenía de fuentes federales un total de unos $8M, hasta alcanzar la cifra de $100M anuales al presente y contar con varios Centros e Institutos de Investigación transdisciplinarios de I+D e Innovación de frontera. Además, la UPR genera el 90% de todas las publicaciones en revistas evaluadas por pares, y trae el 90% de los fondos federales para I+D e Innovación en Puerto Rico. De estos datos se desprende que los tres Recinos Graduados y de Investigación de la UPR son los principales contribuyentes a I+D e Innovación en C&T que Puerto Rico necesita para desarrollar su economía del conocimiento. Claramente, las misiones de estos dos sectores de la Educación Superior se han diferenciado mediante un proceso evolutivo; a su vez, el sector público se ha dividido de facto en dos subsistemas con misiones claramente diferenciadas: los tres recintos Graduados y de Investigación que son dominantes en el I+D e Innovación y la producción de PhD en C&T, y los ocho recintos subgraduados. La Complejidad de la Universidad de Estudios Graduados e Investigación y sus necesidades de una Gerencia Académica, Gobernanza y Administración especializada para cumplir con su misión: Las Universidades de Estudios Graduados e Investigación (EGI) son entidades de un alto grado de complejidad como resultado de su misión especializada e inherentemente competitiva, ya que sus pares se miden en función de su competitividad internacional. El costo de sostener una Universidad de EGI limita su existencia a jurisdicciones con poblaciones de por lo menos cuatro millones de habitantes. A la misma vez, una jurisdicción no puede competir en la economía del conocimiento si no sostiene una de estas Universidades (foro sobre la Universidad de EGI de la AAAS, febrero de 2011). Puerto Rico ya tiene una Universidad de EGI en los recintos de la UPR de Río Piedras, Mayagüez y Ciencias Médicas si se organizan los mismos, salvaguardando sus respectivas autonomías, como un sistema orgánico, coherente y complementario. Los recursos que la Universidad de EGI necesita para ser exitosa son escasos; y, por lo tanto, éstas viven en un mundo que requiere competir continuamente por: estudiantes de alta calidad, profesores/investigadores de reputación internacional, donativos y fondos externos para sostener las investigaciones, y recursos para sostener el ecosistema de investigación que nutre y facilita la productividad intelectual. En este ambiente altamente competitivo, pequeñas diferencias en el talento y habilidad de su plantilla de profesores y la calidad de sus estudiantes se pueden traducir en grandes diferencias en su capacidad para ser exitoso en el mundo de la investigación de frontera. Por estas razones, la Gerencia Académica, Gobernanza y Administración de los recintos Graduados y de Investigación de la UPR tienen que ser altamente ágiles, flexibles y especializadas para que éstas puedan competir en los foros internacionales. Esto hace casi mandatario que la nueva Ley provea para un subsistema de gerencia que cobije a los tres recintos graduados de la UPR. Como resultado de todos estos desarrollos, la Educación Superior en Puerto Rico se encuentra ante un panorama radicalmente diferente al que existía en Puerto Rico en el 1966. La nueva Ley tiene que incorporar esta realidad para optimizar y enriquecer la Educación Superior que es tan importante para el desarrollo económico y cultural de Puerto Rico. 4 RECOMENDACIONES PARA CAMBIOS A LA LEY DEL 1996 RELACIONADOS A LA ARTICULACIÓN Y OPTIMIZACIÓN DEL SISTEMA DE EDUCACIÓN SUPERIOR Y A LA GERENCIA ACADÉMICA, GOBERNANZA Y ADMINISTRACIÓN DE LA UPR Sistema de Educación Superior de Puerto Rico La nueva Ley debe hacer reconocimiento explícito del hecho que la UPR está enmarcada como institución en un Sistema de Educación Superior que tiene un importante y significativo componente de instituciones privadas. Debe proveer un mecanismo que estimule la complementariedad, articulación y optimización del Sistema Público y Privado de Educación Superior de Puerto Rico. En principio y por ley, el Consejo de Educación Superior de Puerto Rico es la entidad que tiene la encomienda de acreditar y evaluar las instituciones de educación superior que operen en Puerto Rico. También tiene la función de llevar a cabo Investigación Institucional del sistema de educación superior y desarrollar una serie de métricas e indicadores para medir la calidad del sistema y su capacidad para servir óptimamente a las necesidades de Puerto Rico (Ley # 213 del 2003). Lo que falta para poder conseguir complementariedad, sinergia, y articulación del sistema de educación superior para que contribuya en forma óptima al desarrollo de Puerto Rico, son mecanismos y estrategias que, respetando la autonomía de todas las instituciones de educación superior, encaucen el desarrollo de nuevos programas y colaboraciones entre el sector privado y público. Además, la nueva Ley de la UPR debe asignarle la responsabilidad al Presidente y Rectores de la UPR de promover y proactivamente facilitar la sinergia, complementariedad y colaboraciones con el sector privado de la Educación Superior. Recomendación: Con el propósito de conseguir complementariedad, sinergia, y articulación del Sistema de Educación Superior para que contribuya en forma óptima al desarrollo de Puerto Rico, se sugiere que el Gobierno asigne un por ciento, o una cantidad a ser fijada de año a año, de fondos de Estado para encauzar el desarrollo del Sistema de Educación Superior en la dirección que mejor sirva a las necesidades del pueblo de Puerto Rico. Estos fondos se distribuirán en forma competitiva entre todas las instituciones del Sistema de Educación Superior en base a propuestas sometidas por las instituciones para competir por los mismos. Los fondos serán de naturaleza germinal y no se podrán utilizar para subsidiar la operación en forma recurrente. Los proponentes deben traer a la mesa fondos de pareo de fuentes federales e institucionales y estarán comprometidos a sostener los nuevos programas o iniciativas una vez los fondos germinales hayan expirado (“sustainability plan”). El Consejo de Educación Superior, o una entidad equivalente, será responsable de determinar las necesidades de nuevos programas o iniciativas que Puerto Rico necesita y, una vez determinadas éstas, emitir convocatorias invitando a las instituciones a competir por los fondos. En el caso de proyectos de I+D e Innovación en Ciencia y Tecnología, se sugiere que el Fideicomiso de Ciencia, Tecnología e Investigación sea la entidad que corra las competencias. 5 Gerencia Académica, Gobernanza y Administración de la UPR La Ley del 1966 utiliza tres conceptos medulares que nunca define y que han sido objeto de diversas interpretaciones y confusión en definir la gerencia académica, gobernanza y administración de la UPR; éstos son: sistema universitario; Plan de Desarrollo Integral; autonomía y descentralización. La nueva ley debe empezar por definir estos tres conceptos que son esenciales para su buen funcionamiento. La Universidad como Sistema Universitario: La Universidad desde el 1966 ha crecido en número, complejidad y diversificación de la misión y metas de de sus unidades o recintos hasta obtener las características de un Sistema Complejo. En el año 2000 se trajo al Dr. Russell L. Ackoff, experto en el estudio de Sistemas Complejos Adaptativos (CAS, por sus siglas en inglés) aplicados a organizaciones; y, después de un retiro en el que participaron el Presidente, Rectores, Decanos y representantes de la facultad, concluyó que la UPR se comportaba como un conglomerado de unidades que no tenían las características de un CAS articulado y optimizado y orquestado para funcionar como un Sistema Orgánico de Educación Superior. La responsabilidad de articular, coordinar y orquestar el funcionamiento óptimo del sistema recae en el Presidente y su cuerpo de Rectores. La Ley provee el mecanismo de la Junta Universitaria como la entidad donde se articule el pensamiento sistémico y la gerencia sistémica de la UPR y le da la encomienda de preparar El Plan de Desarrollo Integral para la UPR que sirva como marco de referencia para guiar su gerencia académica. Después de 45 años y nueve presidentes la UPR todavía esta esperando El Plan de Desarrollo Integral (el documento “Diez para la Década” no llena las especificaciones de un plan integral que sirva de guía para encauzar el sistema). Mientras, la Junta Universitaria, con la disolución del Sistema de Colegios Regionales, creció hasta 38 miembros, un tamaño que no lo hace operacional; de hecho, se ha convertido de facto en un Senado del Sistema que no es funcional, ni capaz de contribuir a la articulación, coordinación y optimización de la UPR para que actúe como un sistema orgánico armónico. Durante este mismo periodo, la UPR—en buena medida por la iniciativa de un grupo emprendedor de profesores/investigadores en los Recintos de Río Piedras, Mayagüez y Ciencias Medicas—se ha diferenciado en dos subsistemas: uno graduado y de investigación, y otro primordialmente subgraduado con misiones y metas dispares que requieren gerencias académicas diferentes. Gerencia Académica al Nivel Sistémico: La nueva Ley de la UPR debe asignarle la responsabilidad indelegable al Presidente de articular, coordinar y optimizar el Sistema Universitario de la UPR para que actúe como un sistema orgánico armónico. Será responsabilidad del Presidente, en forma colegiada con los 11 Rectores del sistema, desarrollar El Plan de Desarrollo Integral con misiones y metas claramente definidas para cada unidad y que éstas se complementen y articulen para optimizar los recursos de la UPR y servir a las necesidades de Puerto Rico. Este plan, por Ley, tendrá que ser sometido a la Junta de Síndicos para su aprobación dentro del periodo de un año después de aprobada la Nueva Ley. 6 Se debe requerir que cada unidad establezca el tipo de institución con el que se desea comparar para medir su progreso en el logro de sus metas (“Benchmarking”). Para el propósito de gerencia académica, se creará un programa de Investigación Institucional Sistémico que establezca y mida las métricas necesarias para medir el progreso de las unidades y el sistema en lograr las misiones y metas plasmadas en el Plan de Desarrollo Integral, y establezca un sistema de rendir cuentas académicas en lograr las metas trazadas por el Plan. El Presidente por Ley tendrá dos Vicepresidentes permanentes, a saber: el Vicepresidente de Asuntos Académicos (VPAA) y el Vicepresidente de Investigación, Estudios Graduados y Tecnología (VPIEGT). Estos serán nombrados por el Presidente y deberán ser confirmados por la Junta de Síndicos y serán puestos de confianza del Presidente. El Presidente podrá nombrar otros Vicepresidentes con funciones gerenciales específicas, según surja la necesidad, previa aprobación para su creación, por la Junta de Síndicos. Estos otros vicepresidentes también requerirán la confirmación de la Junta de Síndicos y serán puestos de confianza del Presidente La Ley reconoce que la UPR tiene dos subsistemas diferenciados por misiones y metas claramente definidas: uno de Estudios Graduados e Investigación (EGI), compuesto por los Recintos de Río Piedras, Mayagüez y Ciencias Médicas, y el otro compuesto por los ocho Recintos, cuya misión primordial es la enseñanza subgraduada. Ambos subsistemas requieren gerencia académica especializada para su articulación y optimización sistémica y para promover sinergia y colaboración entre sus partes. Será función del VPIEGT, por delegación del Presidente, ejercer la gerencia académica del subsistema de EGI, en colaboración directa con los Rectores de los Recintos concernidos para articular, coordinar y optimizar el subsistema de EGI, de manera que éste se comporte como un sistema orgánico armónico. Promover, en colaboración con los Rectores, los estudios e investigaciones multidisciplinarias y transdisciplinarias y la sinergia entre estas unidades para que éstas se comporten como un sistema orgánico de Investigación y Estudios Graduado. El VPIEGT establecerá un programa de Investigación Institucional con las métricas necesarias para medir el progreso del Plan de Desarrollo Institucional en alcanzar sus metas en el área de la Investigación y los Estudios Graduados y, en colaboración con los Rectores, establecerá un sistema para la búsqueda, acopio y administración (“pre- and post-award management”) de fondos para promover los estudios graduados y las investigaciones; establecerá una oficina para la protección de la propiedad intelectual y su comercialización; y será responsable de promover y supervisar el desarrollo de la ciber-infraestructura que dé sostén a la actividad académica, administrativa y de investigación del Sistema Universitario. Será función gerencial académica del VPAA, por delegación del Presidente, ejercer la gerencia académica del subsistema de los ocho Recintos subgraduados, en colaboración directa con los Rectores de los Recintos concernidos para articular, coordinar y optimizar el subsistema de educación subgraduada, de manera que éste se comporte como un sistema orgánico armónico. Promover, en colaboración con los Rectores, el desarrollo de la educación subgraduada de excelencia y la creación de nuevos currículos y grados académicos y profesionales que Puerto Rico necesite para su desarrollo, y la sinergia entre las unidades para que éstas se comporten como un sistema orgánico de enseñanza subgraduada. El VPAA establecerá un programa de Investigación Institucional con las métricas necesarias para medir el progreso del Plan de 7 Desarrollo Institucional en alcanzar sus metas en el área de la educación subgraduada; en colaboración con los Rectores, establecerá un sistema para la búsqueda y acopio de fondos para promover nuevos métodos de enseñanza/aprendizaje y programas que estimulen la excelencia académica. También tendrá a su cargo la coordinación e implantación de todos los procesos de acreditación y certificaciones necesarias para darle rigor y validez a la enseñanza en la UPR. Junta Universitaria: El Presidente con su cuerpo de Rectores, el VPAA y el VPIEGT serán, en forma colegiada y presidido por él, como primus inter pares, el cuerpo rector del Sistema Universitario. Éstos constituirán la Junta Universitaria, la cual incluirá, además, al Director de Finanzas. Con el propósito de dar represtación y participación a la Facultad y a los estudiantes, la Junta Universitaria tendrá dos miembros de la facultad y un estudiante del Sistema Universitario. El estudiante será seleccionado por sus pares de entre los miembros de los Consejos de Estudiantes de los once Recintos. Uno de los profesores será seleccionado de entre los Senadores electos de los tres recintos de EGI de entre sus pares, y el otro será seleccionado de entre los Senadores electos de los ocho Recintos Subgraduados por sus pares. Como Gerente Académico y Administrativo del Sistema, el Presidente tendrá la prerrogativa de reunir y consultar a cualquier subgrupo de la Junta Universitaria y otros oficiales administrativos para los asuntos que él/ella estime pertinente, particularmente aquellos que atañan la articulación y optimización del Sistema Universitario. El ámbito de ingerencia de la Junta serán todos aquellos asuntos que tengan pertinencia para la articulación, coordinación y optimización del Sistema Universitario y que contribuyan al funcionamiento de este como un sistema orgánico armónico y/o que promuevan la sinergia entre sus partes. La Junta Universitaria tendrá las siguientes responsabilidades especificas: 1) Con el insumo de los Planes de Desarrollo Institucionales preparados por las Juntas Administrativas de los once Recintos, bajo el liderato de sus respectivos rectores, desarrollar y aprobar el Plan de Desarrollo Integral del Sistema Universitario, con misiones y metas claras que sean susceptibles de un avalúo racional, de manera que la UPR se desarrolle como un sistema orgánico armónico; 2) Aprobar los planes de Investigación Institucional que preparen el VPAA y VPIEGT; evaluar por lo menos dos veces al año las métricas e informes que resulten de la Investigación Institucional en el contexto del Plan de Desarrollo Institucional; 3) Establecer sistemas de rendir cuentas (“accountability”) académicas y del uso efectivo y eficiente de los recursos fiscales y humanos de la institución; 4) El Presidente, después de recibir los Proyectos de Presupuesto de las Juntas Administrativas de los once Recintos y armonizarlos con los recursos disponibles con el insumo de sus directores de Finazas y Presupuesto, someterá El Proyecto de Presupuesto Sistémico a la Junta Universitaria para su consideración y aprobación antes de someterlo a la consideración y aprobación de la Junta de Síndicos; la Junta Universitaria analizará el presupuesto en el contexto de las misiones y metas de los componentes del Sistema para asegurar una distribución racional de éste. Los once recintos tendrán Juntas Administrativas con un ámbito de ingerencia y funciones análogas a la Junta Universitaria, limitado a su respectivo Recinto. La composición de estas Juntas será igual a lo que se estipula en la presente Ley, la cual asegura representación de profesores y estudiantes en su cuerpo. En adición, las Juntas Administrativas atenderán los asuntos de recursos humanos de su Recinto y la aprobación de permanencia y ascenso, de sabáticas de los profesores y la otorgación de distinciones académicas previa recomendación de sus Senados Académicos, según se describe en la Ley actual. Los Decanos de Facultad y su cuerpo de Directores serán los Gerentes académicos/administrativos de sus respectivas 8 Facultades y presidirán las reuniones de facultad en la misma forma que está plasmado en la presente Ley. El nuevo escalafón Gerencial/Administrativo de la UPR se ilustra en la Fig.2. Gerencia y Gobernanza Académica, Participación de Profesores y Estudiantes: La segunda parte de la Gobernanza de la UPR emana del concepto medieval de las cofradías o gremios artesanales. En el caso de las universidades, éstas cofradías están compuestas por los profesores. Los profesores son responsables por el contenido académico, el ámbito y la calidad de la labor erudita y el I+D y la Innovación, la calidad y la pertinencia de los grados académicos que confiere la institución, la otorgación de grados honoríficos y reconocimientos académicos y contribuir a las acreditaciones de programas académicos. Los profesores también tienen la responsabilidad de participar en la selección de los miembros que han de formar parte de la plantilla de facultativos de la institución, evaluar y recomendar permanencias y ascensos y distinciones conferidas a miembros de la plantilla. En ese sentido, la cofradía de profesores tiene un elemento de autorregulación y es responsable de contribuir a la calidad, efectividad y eficiencia de toda la actividad académica. La participación de los profesores en la gobernanza de la universidad está concentradas en tres organismos: Claustro de Departamento, Claustro de Facultad y Senados Académicos, que tienen los siguientes ámbitos de ingerencia y autoridad. Claustro de Departamento: Será el foro oficial de la comunidad académica de un Departamento, donde se deliberara sobre todos los asuntos académicos de interés para el Departamento. Será función esencial del Claustro asesorar y hacer recomendaciones a la gerencia académica sobre nuevos programas académicos, revisiones curriculares y acreditación de programas; hacer recomendaciones de cómo armonizar y optimizar los ofrecimientos y la actividad académica del Departamento y formas de promover colaboraciones interdisciplinarias y transdisciplinarias dentro del Departamento, con otros departamentos y con otras instituciones académicas; además, tendrá la misión de facilitar y estimular el pensamiento creativo de vanguardia y la sinergia entre sus miembros para promover la excelencia académica, la innovación y la investigación entre sus facultativos y con facultativos de otros departamentos e instituciones. Todos los profesores con nombramientos de carrera en el departamento (“tenure track”) serán miembros del Claustro. El Claustro del Departamento será presidido por su director y gerente académico del mismo. Para darle voz y participación a sus estudiantes en los asuntos académicos departamentales, todo Claustro Departamental tendrá un representante estudiantil electo por los estudiantes del departamento. Comités de Departamento: Los comités de departamento se componen de profesores, electos por sus pares. Su función y ámbito de acción es: evaluar los ofrecimientos académicos: recomendar nuevos programas o enmiendas a los currículos existente; evaluar los candidatos a plazas de profesor en el departamento; evaluar y recomendar la permanencia y los ascensos de profesores. El Claustro Departamental y el Director del Departamento podrán nombrar otros comités para atender asuntos específicos que sean germanos con la actividad académica. Claustro de Facultad: Será el foro oficial de la comunidad académica de una Facultad, donde se deliberará sobre todos los asuntos académicos de interés para la Facultad. Será función esencial 9 del Claustro asesorar y hacer recomendaciones a la gerencia académica sobre nuevos programas académicos, revisiones curriculares y acreditación de programas; hacer recomendaciones de cómo armonizar y optimizar los ofrecimientos y la actividad académica de la Facultad y buscar formas de promover colaboraciones interdisciplinarias y transdisciplinarias dentro de la Facultad, con otras facultades y con otras instituciones académicas. Además, el Claustro tendrá la misión de facilitar y estimular el pensamiento creativo de vanguardia y la sinergia entre sus miembros para promover la excelencia académica, la innovación y la investigación entre sus facultativos y con facultativos de otras Facultades e instituciones. Todos los profesores con nombramientos de carrera (“tenure track”) en la Facultad serán miembros del Claustro de Facultad. El Claustro del Departamento será presidido por el Decano y gerente académico del mismo. Para darles voz y participación a sus estudiantes en los asuntos académicos de Facultad, todo Claustro de Facultad tendrá no más de tres representantes estudiantiles seleccionados de entre sus miembros por los representantes estudiantiles de los departamentos que constituyen la Facultad. Comités de Facultad: Los Decanos de Facultad podrán nombrar o solicitar al Claustro de Profesores que elijan miembros a los comités que el decano o el Claustro de profesores tenga a bien crear para atender asuntos pertinentes al funcionamiento académico de la facultad y la articulación de los componentes de la facultad. Toda Facultad que tenga más de un departamento, centro o instituto tendrá un Comité de Personal que evaluará y hará recomendaciones al Decano sobre las recomendaciones de los Departamentos para permanencia y ascensos, y para sabáticas de Profesores. Senado Académico: Los Senados Académicos serán el foro oficial de la comunidad académica de un Recinto, donde se deliberarán sobre todos los asuntos académicos de interés para el Recinto. Será función esencial de los Senados Académicos asesorar y hacer recomendaciones a la gerencia académica sobre nuevos programas académicos, revisiones curriculares y acreditación de programas; hacer recomendaciones de cómo armonizar y optimizar los ofrecimientos y la actividad académica del Recinto, y formas de promover colaboraciones interdisciplinarias y transdisciplinarias dentro del Recinto y con otras instituciones académicas. También tendrá la responsabilidad de establecer los requisitos generales de admisión, promoción y graduación de los estudiantes; seleccionar de entre sus miembros electos dos representantes a la Junta Administrativa y participar en la selección de uno de los representantes de la facultad a la Junta Universitaria; hacer recomendaciones a la gerencia académica sobre la creación y otorgación de distinciones académicas; y recibir, analizar y hacer recomendaciones al Rector sobre el informe periódico que éste haga al pleno del Senado sobre el estado de situación de la institución. El Senado Académico de un Recinto estará constituido por los siguientes miembros ex oficio: el Decano de Asuntos Académicos; el Decano de Estudiantes; el Director de la Biblioteca o su equivalente; los Decanos de Facultad y, en el caso de los Recintos de EGI, el Decano de Estudios Graduados e Investigaciones (DEGI) o su equivalente. Cada Facultad o Escuela del Recinto elegirá un miembro al Senado Académico de entre sus miembros que no ocupe una posición gerencial académica o administrativa. Las facultades que tengan una matricula estudiantil que exceda el 10% de la matricula total del Recinto tendrán derecho a elegir un segundo senador para que lo represente en el Senado; en el caso de las facultades que tengan programas graduados, el 10 segundo senador será miembro de uno de sus programas graduados. El término para un senador electo será de dos años, y ningún senador podrá servir más de dos términos consecutivos. Para dar voz y representación al cuerpo de estudiantes, El Consejo de Estudiantes del Recinto elegirá a dos de sus miembros para que lo represente en el Senado Académico. Estos estudiantes tendrán los mismos derechos y prerrogativas que los Senadores electos por las Facultades. Por ser el Senado Académico el foro oficial de la comunidad académica de un Recinto, el mismo será presidido por el Decano de Asuntos Académicos; en el caso de los Recintos EGI, el Rector podrá nombrar al Decano del DEGI o su equivalente como presidente del Senado en substitución del Decano de Asuntos Académicos. El Rector del Recinto asistirá una vez por semestre a una reunión del Senado Académico para dar un informe sobre el estado de situación de la institución y dialogar con el Senado sobre cualquier otro asunto apremiante que estime pertinente; en esa ocasión asumirá la Presidencia del Senado. De considerarlo necesario, informará al Presidente del Senado que convoque al mismo a otras reuniones extraordinarias para discutir la agenda que él estime pertinente, en cuya ocasión se desempeñará como el Presidente del Senado. El presidente de la UPR, previa solicitud y con la anuencia del Rector, podrá dirigirse a cualquier Senado Académico del Sistema Universitario para atender la agenda que él estime pertinente. El Presidente del Senado convocará a una reunión extraordinaria para ese propósito, la cual será presidida por el Presidente de la UPR. Los profesores participan en la gobernanza de la universidad a través de su participación en los Claustros de Departamento, Claustro de Facultad y Senados Académicos, y a través de la representación que éstos tienen en las Juntas Administrativas, la Junta Universitaria y la Junta de Síndicos que forman el espinazo de la estructura jerárquica gerencial/administrativa de la institución. Autonomía y Descentralización Autonomía: La Ley del 1996 utiliza el vocablo “autonomía” cinco veces en el texto de la Ley sin definirlo. Esto ha causado un alto grado de confusión en la comunidad universitaria que tiende a interpretarla como equivalente a una independencia virtual que da derecho al que la utiliza a actuar sin rendir cuentas por sus acciones. Es mandatario que la nueva Ley defina este término y encomiende al Presidente de la UPR y sus rectores a definir el alcance, ámbito y limitación del vocablo “autonomía” cuando lo utilicen en delinear las estructuras de gerencia/administración fiscal y académicas. La palabra “autonomía” se utiliza con dos significados diferentes en la Ley: El primer significado atañe a su autonomía de gobernanza gerencial/administrativa y fiscal, y su capacidad para generar un plan de desarrollo integral que le permite a la Universidad actuar sin interferencias indebidas del Gobierno Estatal en sus asuntos internos. Como Universidad Pública que recibe fondos a través de la Formula del 9.6% del Fondo General del Gobierno para financiar sus operaciones, la Universidad 11 tiene una responsabilidad ineludible de responder a las necesidades de Puerto Rico y a las Políticas Públicas del Gobierno, salvaguardando la libertad de cátedra de los profesores y su autonomía interna. La interpretación de dónde está la línea que separa a la responsabilidad de la Universidad de responder a las necesidades del Estado, los reclamos o peticiones de acción que pueda hacerle el Gobierno y la autonomía interna de la Universidad, le corresponde a la Junta de Síndicos, como representantes del interés publico, en consulta con el Presidente de la UPR. La dependencia de la Universidad de Puerto Rico de los fondos del Estado es la mayor de todas las universidades del Estado de los Estados Unidos. Esta dependencia, sin menoscabo de los fondos que provienen del Estado, debe reducirse para aumentar su autonomía fiscal mediante el estímulo de la autogestión. La Universidad, por medio de su Presidente y Rectores, tiene la responsabilidad de promover y facilitar la auto-gestión de los profesores, la práctica intra-mural, el desarrollo de programas auto-liquidables, la búsqueda de fondos externos, la comercialización de la innovación, el desarrollo de un fondo dotal y cualquier otra estrategia que aumenten los ingresos de la institución, en adición a los fondos que provienen del Estado, para incrementar su solvencia y autonomía fiscal. El segundo significado atañe a la autonomía relativa de los Recintos relativos a la Universidad de Puerto Rico como Sistema Universitario. La definición formal que aplica a este tipo de autonomía proviene del estudio del ordenamiento de organizaciones, y lee como sigue: autonomía se puede definir como el grado al cual una subunidad de una organización o gerente académico/administrativo puede actuar sin el consentimiento previo de otros (International Journal of Business and Economics, 2003, Vol. 2, #1, 5773). La Universidad de Puerto Rico, como sistema complejo y adaptativo (CAS), debe promover la autonomía máxima posible hasta los niveles donde las decisiones se puedan tomar en la forma más expedita, eficiente y efectiva sin menoscabo a la integridad del Sistema Universitario. Le corresponde a los Rectores y al Presidente en forma colegiada definir y proveer los mecanismos para implantar la autonomía relativa de los Recintos, Decanatos y Departamentos. Para que esta autonomía sea funcional se requiere que todos los recintos hayan definido con claridad su misión y metas que sean medibles y auditables, y que se haya aprobado el Plan de Desarrollo Integral que articule el Sistema en uno armónico y optimizado. Para poder auditar la efectividad y eficiencia de la delegación de autoridad y responsabilidades a los distintos niveles del sistema es esencial el desarrollo pleno de la Investigación Institucional, con métricas medibles, y un sistema riguroso de rendir cuentas (“accountability”) académicas y fiscales. El sistema de rendir cuentas y las auditorias, al final de cada año, determinarán el grado de autonomía autorizada y, de ser necesario por falta de efectividad y eficiencia, la restricción o eliminación de la autonomía relativa a las unidades que no hagan buen uso de ésta. Descentralización: El vocablo “descentralización” aparece una sola vez en la Ley del 1966, utilizado en la siguiente forma: “Descentralización del Sistema Universitario”. Si la descentralización era necesaria en el 1966, ahora, 45 años después, la necesidad de descentralizar es aún más apremiante. La UPR no es solo un Sistema Complejo Adaptativo (CAS) por la nolinealidad de sus interacciones y retroalimentaciones entre todos los niveles del sistema, sino que 12 ahora es un sistema sumamente “complicado” que está compuesto por 11 Recintos semiautónomos dispares; y cada uno, a su vez, está compuesto de múltiples Departamentos, Facultades y Escuelas y, ahora, también incluye Institutos y Centros de Investigación, Innovación y Labor Creadora. Tratar de operar un sistema tan complicado en forma centralizada, donde toda la autoridad y poder decisional se encuentre en la gerencia académica/administrativa del nivel más alto es patentemente inoperante y lleva a grandes ineficiencias e inefectividad. Una vez completado el Plan de Desarrollo Integral establecido, el sistema de Investigación Institucional, las métricas para medir el logro de su misión y metas, un sistema de rendir cuentas académicas y fiscales, y auditorias periódicas del sistema para medir la efectividad y eficiencia del mismo, el Presidente con su cuerpo de Rectores, en forma colegiada, establecerán e implantarán un proceso de descentralización. Este proceso esta íntimamente correlacionado con los grados de autonomía que se le asignen a los distintos componentes del sistema. Será responsabilidad del Presidente con su cuerpo de Rectores asegurar que se salvaguarde la articulación, coordinación y optimización del Sistema Universitario para que éste actúe en forma coherente y armónica, y pueda responder a los retos internos y externos. Cuando la descentralización demuestre que es contraproducente para el buen funcionamiento de la institución, será responsabilidad del Presidente y los Rectores revertir el proceso de descentralización. Será función esencial del proceso de descentralización y su implementación, el estimular y facilitar la formación de redes de comunicación y alianzas estratégicas entre profesores, departamentos y con otras instituciones para estimular la formación de Centros, Institutos y proyectos interdisciplinarios y transdisciplinarios. También creará los espacios creadores que fomenten la autogestión y la comercialización de la propiedad intelectual. Proceso de Consulta La Ley del 1966 menciona la palabra “consulta” cuatro veces relativo al nombramiento de la gerencia académica/administrativa: Rectores, Decanos y Directores de Departamento, y se refiere a la creación de un sistema de consulta para el nombramiento del Presidente. Contrario a los conceptos de autonomía y descentralización, la consulta se define en el Art.15, (a) (9). Sin embargo, la definición no ha impedido que la consulta sea fuente de discordia entre la facultad y la gerencia académica/administrativa y la Junta de Síndicos. En el último análisis, nadie está satisfecho con el sistema y procedimientos de consulta: la autoridad nominadora, porque entiende que tiene la prerrogativa final de nombrar al que él/ella entienda que es la persona más apropiada para el puesto o porque es la persona de su confianza; algunos sectores de la facultad, por sentirse que “no se honró la consulta” cuando entienden que no se actúo de acuerdo a sus recomendaciones; y para algunos sectores porque equiparan la consulta a una elección de la gerencia académica/administrativa. Según se ha complicado la gerencia académica/administrativa y la naturaleza inherentemente compleja del sistema híbrido de gerencia académica, que contiene un elemento jerárquico administrativo y una gobernanza de participación activa de la facultad, la gerencia académica/administrativa requiere un proceso de desarrollo y peritaje que el profesor promedio 13 no posee. Por esto, las grandes universidades, particularmente las de EGI, tienen mecanismos para desarrollar en forma incremental su gerencia académica/administrativa o reclutarla de otras instituciones de educación superior. Por esta razones, el proceso insatisfactorio de “consulta” se substituirá por uno de “Búsqueda, Evaluación y Selección”. El proceso de “Búsqueda, Evaluación y Selección” (BES) se implantará mediante la creación de un Comité de BES que estará constituido por tres miembros que seleccionará la autoridad nominadora (Junta de Síndicos para el Presidente, el Presidente y la Junta de Síndicos para Rectores, el Rector para Decanos, y el Decano para Directores de Departamento), un miembro de la facultad seleccionado por el cuerpo correspondiente de gobernanza de la facultad (Senado(s) Académico(s), Claustros de Facultad, o Claustros de Departamento) y por un estudiante seleccionado por los Consejo(s) de Estudiante(s) o el cuerpo correspondiente a nivel de Facultad o Departamento. Será la encomienda y responsabilidad del Comité BES, en un término a ser fijado por la autoridad nominadora, de llevar a cabo las siguientes funciones: (1) en consulta con la autoridad nominadora y siguiendo de cerca la misión y metas del Plan de Desarrollo Integral o el de la unidad correspondiente, establecer el perfil de la persona que se desea reclutar para la posición gerencial académica/administrativa; (2) iniciar una búsqueda proactiva y amplia en y fuera de la institución de candidatos que llenen los requisitos del perfil deseado; (3) entrevistar los candidatos que soliciten la posición y evaluar su plan de trabajo, su experiencia gerencial académica/administrativa y sus credenciales académicas; (4) será responsabilidad del representante de la facultad y el estudiante recibir y recopilar el insumo de sus respectivos constituyentes después de haber difundido el plan de trabajo y las credenciales de los candidatos mediante una pagina de web; y (5) seleccionar todos los candidatos que llenen el perfil deseado y someter sus recomendaciones a la autoridad nominadora. Será la responsabilidad indelegable de la autoridad nominadora hacer la selección final y nombrar el candidato seleccionado. En adición la Ley, requerirá que se establezca un plan de sucesión (“succession plan”) para desarrollar y cultivar un cohorte de gerentes académicos/administrativos que tengan las destrezas, liderato y experiencia para ocupar las posiciones de gerencia académica/administrativa a todos los niveles, según surjan vacantes. Términos fijos para los nombramientos, evaluación y plan de sucesión de los Gerentes Académicos/Administrativos: Todos los gerentes académicos/administrativos serán nombrados por términos fijos por la autoridad nominadora. Los términos serán los siguientes: seis años para el Presidente; cinco años para los Rectores y Decanos; y tres años para los Directores de Departamento. La autoridad nominadora evaluará en forma exhaustiva la gestión del gerente académico/administrativo un año y medio antes de finalizar su término, basado en el plan de trabajo que el gerente académico/administrativo propuso cuando comenzó su término, y su ejecutoria y liderato en contribuir al Plan de Desarrollo Institucional de su unidad y el Integral del Sistema de la UPR. La autoridad nominadora, basándose en la evaluación del gerente académico/administrativo, podrá extender el nombramiento de éste por un término adicional para que complete su plan de trabajo, que no excederá los siguientes límites: tres años para el Presidente; dos años para Rectores y Decanos; y un año para directores de Departamento. Todos los gerentes académicos serán puestos de confianza de la autoridad nominadora y podrán ser removidos de sus puestos antes de finalizar su término cuando éstos no estén cumpliendo 14 cabalmente con sus responsabilidades, o cometan faltas que no son consistentes con la conducta apropiada de un académico, o violen la Ley de Ética Gubernamental. Para asegurar la continuidad del sistema gerencial académico/administrativo, será responsabilidad de la autoridad nominadora constituir un comité de BES para reclutar al sucesor del gerente académico/administrativo un año antes de que éste finalice su término. Sistema de Conocimiento, Información y Datos Vitales que Reflejen el Estado del Sistema Universitario a todos sus Niveles La sana gerencia de un sistema complejo como la UPR requiere que todo conocimiento, información y datos vitales que caractericen y describan el estado del sistema sea accesible y transparente a todos los miembros de la Comunidad Universitaria y al pueblo de Puerto Rico. Será la responsabilidad indelegable del Presidente con su cuerpo de Rectores y Vicepresidentes establecer un Sistema de Conocimiento, Informaron y Datos Vitales (SCID) que logre este propósito, y que el mismo esté disponible mediante una página de Web para asegurar su diseminación amplia y transparente a toda la Comunidad Universitaria y al Pueblo de Puerto Rico. El VPIEGT, que es responsable de la ciber-infraestructura del Sistema, en estrecha colaboración con el VPAA, será directamente responsable de establecer el SCID; y todos los gerentes académicos/administrativos tendrán la responsabilidad de suplir la información y datos vitales para mantener el SCID actualizado. El SCID contendrá por lo menos la siguiente información que rinda una descripción fiel del estado de la institución en su desarrollo académico y sus estados financieros: los Planes de Desarrollo Integral del Sistema y los Institucionales de los Recintos; todos los datos vitales e información que emane de la Investigación Institucional y los informes que resulten de sus investigaciones; todos los estudios que resulten de la comparación con los pares que los Recintos y el Sistema utilice para medir el progreso en alcanzar sus metas de desarrollo académico; los informes periódicos del estado de situación del Sistema y los Recintos que el Presidente y los Rectores tienen la responsabilidad de emitir para comunicarse con sus respectivos constituyentes; el presupuesto anual de la Institución; y los estados financieros certificados de la Institución. La gerencia académica/administrativa de un sistema tan complejo como el de la UPR requiere que la información y datos vitales necesarios para la toma de decisiones y para el avalúo de la actividad académica y fiscal fluyan en forma expedita, transparente y exacta de la alta gerencia hasta la base del sistema gerencial y, en forma recíproca, de la base hasta la alta gerencia. Será responsabilidad del Presidente y de los Rectores, con el peritaje de sus administradores y expertos en ciber-infraestructura, establecer un sistema de información y datos que permitan una gerencia que esté en cumplimiento con las metas institucionales y que utilice en forma efectiva y eficiente los recursos institucionales. Este sistema, que es necesario para la toma racional de decisiones, contendrá la información y datos vitales necesarios para: el establecimiento de prioridades académicas, presupuestarias y fiscales; las auditorías académicas y las auditorías sobre el uso óptimo y efectivo de los recursos fiscales y de infraestructura de sostén para la actividad académica e investigativa; y para medir y avaluar el cumplimento de la institución con la misión y las metas trazadas en los Planes de Desarrollo de cada unidad y del sistema. 4-28-11 (2:57 PM) Figura 1a Organigrama Esquemático de la UPR y sus Recintos Junta de Síndicos Grupo de Trabajo con Rectores Junta Universitaria Presidente Sistema UPR Gerencia y Administración del Sistema Universitario (Ver Diagrama Organizacional Adjunto) Senado Académico Rector 1 Decano Director Departamento … … Junta Administrativa Decano Director Departamento … … … Rector 11 Figura 1b Organigrama Institucional Universidad de Puerto Rico Administración Central Junta de Síndicos Junta de Apelaciones no Docentes Vicepresidencia en Investigación y Tecnología Editorial UPR • Investigación • Centro de Recursos, Ciencia e Ingeniería • Institutos de Investigación • Propiedad Intelectual y Patentes • Sistemas de Información • Internet 2 • Proyecto Transferencia en Tecnología • Atlantea Presidente Vicepresidencia en Asuntos Académicos Junta Universitaria Ayudantes • Plan de desarrollo • Investigación Institucional • Programas Académicos • Licencias • Acreditación • Reconocimiento de Grado Asuntos Legales Vicepresidencia en Asuntos Estudiantiles • Vinculación Preuniversitaria • Admisiones • Asistencia Económica • Servicios Estudiantiles y Clima Institucional • Programa Cultural • Proyectos especiales Junta de Síndicos Oficina Desarrollo y Exalumnos • Relaciones Universitarias • Relaciones Gubernamentales • Exalumnos • Desarrollo • Asuntos Federales JS de Compras Oficina Servicios Administrativos • Compras • Propiedad • Seguridad • Imprenta • Adm. de Documentos • Servicios Generales • Sistemas y Procedimientos Oficina Finanzas • Finanzas • Nómina • Contabilidad • Seguros • Recaudaciones • Adm. Fiscal de Recursos Externos • Adm. Efectivos e Inversiones • Área Fiscal de Asist. Económica Oficina Recursos Humanos • Certificación y Retribución • Reclutamiento • Beneficios Marginales y Licencias • Asesoramiento Laboral • Centro Pre-escolar Oficina Presupuesto Junta de Diseño Oficina Desarrollo Físico y Infraestructura • Diseño y Construcción • Jardín Botánico • Calidad Ambiental y Seguridad Ocupacional JS Mejoras Permanentes Figura 2 Esquema Gerencial Administrativo de la Ley UPR en una Nueva Ley Junta de Síndicos Junta Universitaria Presidente Sistema UPR Subsistema de Recintos de Estudios Graduados e Investigación [3 Recintos] Subsistema de Recintos Subgraduados [8 Recintos] VPAA Articulación del Subsistema VPI EGT Articulación del Subsistema … Junta Administrativa … Rector 1 Rector 1 … … Decano Director Departamento Decano VPA: Vicepresidente de Asuntos Académicos VPIEGT: Vicepresidente de Investigación, Estudios Graduados y Tecnología Director Departamento Junta Administrativa Naturaleza y Funciones de la Junta Universitaria en el Contexto de la Organización de la UPR Jorge A. Cruz Emeric, Ph. D. Secretario Ejecutivo Junta Universitaria 4 de septiembre de 2007. 1 Objetivos Repasar la estructura organizacional de la Universidad. Entender el ámbito de acción de los diversos cuerpos y funcionarios que componen la organización Entender cómo encaja la Junta Universitaria dentro de ese esquema organizacional. 2 Base legal de la Universidad Corporación pública. Estructura y gobierno definida por la Ley #1 del 20 de enero de 1966. Leyes importantes Ley #1 del 20 de enero de 1966 Ley #2 del 20 de enero de 1966 Ley #16 del 16 de junio de 1993 3 Ley #1 del 20 de enero de 1966 Ley de la Universidad de Puerto Rico. La Ley define las funciones de los diversos cuerpos y funcionarios ejecutivos, las facultades corporativas de la organización. Consejo de Educación Superior (Hoy Junta de Síndicos) Junta Universitaria Senado Académico Junta Administrativa Claustro Estudiantado 4 Ley #16 del 16 de junio de 1993 Enmienda la Ley Num. 1 del 20 de enero de 1966 para eliminar al Consejo de Educación Superior como cuerpo rector y crear la Junta de Síndicos de la Universidad de Puerto Rico. La Ley define la composición de la Junta de Síndicos, sus deberes y atribuciones. 5 Estructura de gobierno del Sistema El gobierno central de la institución es responsabilidad de: La Junta de Síndicos -- es el máximo cuerpo ejecutivo. El Presidente de la Universidad -- es el principal oficial ejecutivo. La Junta Universitaria -- integra al sistema universitario. 6 Diagrama organizacional del sistema Junta de Síndicos de la Universidad de Puerto Rico Oficina de Auditores Internos Junta del Fondo de Retiro de la Universidad de Puerto Rico Presidente de la Universidad de Puerto Rico Junta Universitaria Rector de Unidad Institucional Autónoma Cuerpos deliberativos y funcionarios de la unidad insitucional 7 Estructura de gobierno de la Unidad Institucional El gobierno en cada unidad institucional es responsabilidad de: Rector -- es el principal oficial ejecutivo del campus Senado Académico -- se concentra mayormente en asuntos de la academia. Junta Administrativa -- se concentra mayormente en asuntos administrativos y de distribución de recursos. 8 Diagrama organizacional de la unidad institucional Junta de Síndicos Presidente Junta Universitaria Rector Junta Administrativa Decanos Institucionales Senado Académico Decano de As. Acad. Oficinas bajo Rectoría Decano Facultad Claustro de la Facultad Director de Departamento Claustro del Departamento 9 Interacción Cada cuerpo y funcionario tiene su ámbito de acción. No hay conflicto entre funcionarios y cuerpos cuando cada uno entiende su rol y trabaja en armonía con el resto de la organización. 10 Deberes y atribuciones La Ley de la Universidad de Puerto Rico define los deberes y atribuciones de cada cuerpo deliberativo y de los funcionarios ejecutivos de mayor jerarquía. El Reglamento General de la Universidad de Puerto Rico precisa con mayor detalle los deberes y atribuciones de los funcionarios y de los cuerpos deliberativos. La Junta de Síndicos asigna o especifica deberes y atribuciones dentro del marco de la Ley mediante certificaciones. 11 Junta de Síndicos 12 Junta de Síndicos: Deberes y atribuciones Según la Ley 16: Planificación: Aprobar el plan de desarrollo integral de la Universidad y revisarlo anualmente. Desarrollo del sistema: Autorizar la creación, modificación y reorganización de recintos, centros y otras unidades institucionales. Reglamentación: aprobar o enmendar el Reglamento General de la Universidad, el Reglamento General de Estudiantes, el Reglamento de Estudiantes de cada recinto y cualquier otro reglamento de aplicación general. 13 Junta de Síndicos: Deberes y atribuciones Estructura gerencial: Disponer la creación y eliminación de cargos de funcionarios auxiliares del Presidente de la Universidad. Autorizar la creación y eliminación de cargos de decanos que no presidan facultades. Apelaciones: Resolver las apelaciones que se interpusieran contra las decisiones del Presidente, de la Junta Universitaria y de la Junta de Apelaciones del personal técnico administrativo en el sistema universitario. 14 Junta de Síndicos: Deberes y atribuciones Nombrar funcionarios: Nombrar en consulta con los Senados Académicos u organismos equivalentes de las respectivas unidades, al Presidente de la Universidad de Puerto Rico y a los rectores de las unidades autónomas. Aprobar los nombramientos del Director de Finanzas y de aquellos otros funcionarios auxiliares del Presidente de la Universidad que requieran su aprobación. Establecer los procedimientos para la sustitución temporal de los funcionarios universitarios. 15 Junta de Síndicos: Deberes y atribuciones Presupuesto y distribución de recursos: Considerar y aprobar el proyecto de presupuesto del sistema universitario que le someta el Presidente anualmente, Aprobar y mantener un sistema de contabilidad y auditoria para el uso de los fondos de la Universidad conforme a la ley y los reglamentos. Rendir anualmente al Gobernador y la Asamblea Legislativa un informe acerca de sus gestiones y del estado y finanzas de la Universidad. 16 Junta de Síndicos: Deberes y atribuciones Administrar beneficios del personal universitario Adoptar normas respecto a los derechos y deberes del personal universitario. Fijar sueldos y emolumentos a los funcionarios de la Universidad nombrados por la propia Junta. Mantener un plan de seguro médico y un sistema de pensiones para todo el personal universitario, el cual incluirá un plan de préstamos. Establecer normas generales para la concesión de becas y cualquier otra ayuda económica en el sistema universitario público. 17 Junta de Síndicos: Deberes y atribuciones Crear y otorgar distinciones académicas por su propia iniciativa o a propuesta de los Senados Académicos. Adoptar un reglamento interno. Organizar su oficina, contratar y nombrar el personal necesario para ejercer las facultades que se le señalan por la ley. 18 Presidente de la Universidad 19 Presidente de la UPR Principal oficial ejecutivo de la institución. Debe armonizar las iniciativas de los funcionarios y organismos del sistema y tomar sus propias iniciativas para promover el desarrollo de la Universidad, particularmente en aquellas actividades que rebasen los límites de una unidad institucional. Con la colaboración de la Junta Universitaria coordinará y supervisará las labores universitarias logrando la integración del sistema. 20 Presidente: Deberes y atribuciones Como principal oficial ejecutivo: Hacer cumplir los objetivos, normas, reglamentos y planes presupuestarios desarrollados para la Universidad. Representar oficialmente la Universidad. Presidir la Junta Universitaria. Someter a la Junta de Síndicos los reglamentos de aplicación general y todos aquellos acuerdos de la Junta Universitaria que requieran su aprobación. Establecer y mantener relaciones con universidades y centros de cultura de Puerto Rico y del exterior. 21 Presidente: Deberes y atribuciones Rol de planificación: Formular con el asesoramiento de la Junta Universitaria y someter a la consideración de la Junta de Síndicos, el plan de desarrollo integral de la Universidad y sus revisiones anuales, a base de los proyectos y recomendaciones originados en las unidades institucionales autónomas. Formular el proyecto de presupuesto integrado para todo el sistema universitario basado en los proyectos de presupuesto que sometan los rectores y directores, una vez aprobado por las Juntas Administrativas de las unidades institucionales autónomas, y someter el mismo con las recomendaciones de la Junta Universitaria a la consideración y aprobación de la Junta de Síndicos. Rendir un informe anual a la Junta de Síndicos sobre todos los aspectos de la vida universitaria. 22 Presidente: Deberes y atribuciones Autoridad nominadora: Someter a la Junta de Síndicos los nombramientos de los rectores de las unidades institucionales autónomas., del Director de Finanzas y de aquellos otros funcionarios que requieren la confirmación de aquella. Nombrar y contratar el personal técnico y administrativo de su oficina, y de dependencias universitarias que no estén bajo la jurisdicción administrativa de cualquier recinto siguiendo las disposiciones de la Ley. Resolver las apelaciones que se interpusieren contra las decisiones de los rectores y directores. Es miembro ex-officio de los Claustros, Senados Académicos y Juntas Administrativas del sistema universitario. 23 Junta Universitaria 24 Integración del sistema: función esencial Mantener integrado el sistema universitario, respecto a la planificación de conjunto. Asesorar al Presidente en la coordinación de la marcha de las diferentes unidades institucionales en lo referente a aspectos académicos, administrativos y financieros. Administración Claustro Estudiantado 25 Junta Universitaria: Deberes y atribuciones De acuerdo a la Ley de la Universidad: Considerar el plan de desarrollo de la Universidad que le someta el Presidente, y formular las recomendaciones que juzgue pertinentes sobre el mismo, para la consideración de la Junta de Síndicos. Considerar el proyecto de presupuesto integrado para el sistema universitario según haya sido formulado por el Presidente de la Universidad para ser sometido a la Junta de Síndicos, y formular las recomendaciones que juzgue pertinentes. Resolver las apelaciones que se interpusieran contra las decisiones de las Juntas Administrativas y de los Senados Académicos de cada recinto. 26 Junta Universitaria: Deberes y atribuciones De acuerdo al Reglamento General: Colaborar con el Presidente en la gestión de dirigir el sistema universitario. Asesorar al presidente en cuestiones de política general institucional del sistema. Mantener informado al Presidente sobre el sentir de los diversos sectores del Sistema en cuanto a las cuestiones principales que afecten la vida académica. Proponer para la consideración del Presidente, o para que éste eleve a la Junta de Síndicos con sus recomendaciones, medidas de política institucional. 27 Junta Universitaria: Deberes y atribuciones Hacer recomendaciones al Presidente o a la Junta de Síndicos sobre todos aquellos asuntos que el Presidente o la Junta de Síndicos le someta, o a su propia iniciativa. Hacer recomendaciones a la Junta de Síndicos, a través del Presidente, sobre las propuestas que surjan de las juntas administrativas y senados académicos que requieran acción de la Junta de Síndicos. Academia Recursos Fiscales Administración 28 Unidad autónoma 29 Rector El Rector ejerce la autoridad máxima administrativa y académica dentro del ámbito de su unidad institucional conforme a lo dispuesto por la Ley y las normas y reglamentos universitarios. El Rector es nominado por el Presidente, previa consulta de éste a su respectivo Senado Académico. Su nombramiento debe ser aprobado por la Junta de Síndicos. El Rector sirve a la voluntad del Presidente y la Junta de Síndicos. 30 Claustro Compuesto por el Rector, (lo preside), los decanos y los miembros del personal docente. Dividido según organización aprobada por la Junta de Síndicos. El Reglamento General define las funciones y prerrogativas del Claustro. Participación claustral se da a través de: Senado Académico Facultad Departamento 31 Senado Académico Foro oficial de la comunidad académica para discutir los problemas generales que interesen a la marcha de la Universidad y para los asuntos sobre los cuales tienen jurisdicción. Mediante representantes electos, el Senado representa al claustro ante la Junta Administrativa, Junta Universitaria y Junta de Retiro. 32 Senado Académico: Deberes y atribuciones Planificación Académica Determinar la orientación general de los programas de enseñanza e investigación en la unidad institucional, coordinando las iniciativas de las facultades y departamentos. Establecer los requisitos generales de admisión, promoción y graduación de los estudiantes. 33 Senado Académico: Deberes y atribuciones Reglamentación Establecer para su inclusión en el Reglamento General las normas generales de ingreso, permanencia, promoción de rango y licencias de los miembros del Claustro. Hacer recomendaciones a la Junta Universitaria relativas a enmiendas al Reglamento General de la Universidad que esta le proponga. Someter a la Junta Universitaria, con sus recomendaciones, asuntos relacionados con el Reglamento de Estudiantes. Establecer normas generales sobre todos aquellos asuntos de la unidad institucional pero que no envuelvan responsabilidades institucionales en común. 34 Senado Académico: Deberes y atribuciones Consulta y asesoramiento Entender en consultas relativas a los nombramientos de los rectores y directores, y de los decanos que no presidan facultades. Elegir a sus representantes ante la Junta Universitaria y la Junta Administrativa. Hacer recomendaciones a la Junta de Síndicos relativas a la creación o reorganización de facultades, escuelas o dependencias. Hacer recomendaciones a la Junta de Síndicos relativas a la creación y otorgamiento de distinciones académicas. Rendir anualmente un informe de su labor a los Claustros correspondientes. 35 Junta Administrativa: Deberes y atribuciones Asesorar al rector en el ejercicio de sus funciones. Elaborar proyectos y planes de desarrollo de la unidad institucional. Considerar el proyecto de presupuesto de la unidad. Conceder, a propuesta del rector, las licencias, rangos, ascensos en rango académico y la permanencia del personal docente y técnico de la unidad institucional conforme a lo dispuesto por el Reglamento General de la UPR. Aparte de las funciones que le asigna la Ley, esta junta actuará como cuerpo consultivo del Rector y colaborará con éste en la realización del programa universitario. (Sección 24.6) 36 Facultad: Deberes y atribuciones Planificación Académica Proponer al Senado Académico programas académicos y proyectos de extensión y educación continuada. Tomar acuerdos para intensificar las labores de la facultad, a fin de hacer más efectivo el cumplimiento de los objetivos para los cuales ha sido creada la Universidad. Recomendar al Senado Académico, para su consideración y trámite a los organismos correspondientes, la creación, eliminación, o reorganización de dependencias o departamentos adscritos a su unidad respectiva. Elegir sus senadores académicos. 37 Facultad: Deberes y atribuciones Asesoramiento Exponer sus puntos de vista al Rector para que este los considere y los someta con sus recomendaciones a quien corresponda, sobre todo asunto relacionado con el funcionamiento de la facultad, el Recinto o el Sistema Universitario. Participar en los procesos de consulta para nombramientos, ascensos, permanencias, licencias del personal docente y cuestiones presupuestarias, a través de los mecanismos establecidos para esos propósitos. Recomendar, los nombres de los candidatos a grados universitarios de la facultad correspondiente. Proponer al Senado Académico el otorgamiento de distinciones académicas y honoríficas a ser otorgadas por la Junta de Síndicos. 38 Departamento: Deberes y atribuciones El Reglamento General le asigna al departamento: Llegar a acuerdos y hacer recomendaciones para lograr el desarrollo más efectivo de los objetivos departamentales según la disciplina, incluyendo el establecimiento de normas educacionales Aprobar los programas de estudio de su unidad para su consideración por la facultad. 39 Estudiantado Conforme a lo dispuesto por la Ley de la Universidad de Puerto Rico, los estudiantes son considerados parte de la comunidad universitaria. El Reglamento General de Estudiantes define: Los derechos y deberes de los estudiantes Su participación en los procesos de toma de decisiones por medio del Consejo de Estudiantes La representación estudiantil ante las reuniones de departamento, facultad, Senado Académico, Junta Administrativa y Junta Universitaria. 40 Resumen Cada cuerpo y funcionario tiene su ámbito de acción. No hay conflicto entre funcionarios y cuerpos cuando cada uno entiende su rol y trabaja en armonía con el resto de la organización. 41 TheCenter The Top American Research Universities John V. Lombardi Diane D. Craig Elizabeth D. Capaldi Denise S. Gater Sarah L. Mendonça July 2001 An Annual Report from The Lombardi Program on Measuring University Performance Copyright 2001, TheCenter at the University of Florida Contents Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .3 The University . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5 The American Research University: A Perspective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5 American Higher Education and the Research University . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5 Quality Engines: The American Research University Prototype . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .7 The Competitive Context for Research Universities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .12 Measuring Institutional Competitiveness for Research Universities . . . . . . . . . . . . .19 Ranking and Measuring . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .19 The Impact of Enrollment and Medical Schools on Research Competitiveness . . .25 Change in Competitive Performance on Federal Research . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .30 Data Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .37 Part I: The Top American Research Universities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .37 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .37 Universities Ranking in Top 25 Nationally . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .38 Universities Ranking in Top 26–50 Nationally . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .40 Private Universities Ranking in Top 25 among Privates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .42 Public Universities Ranking in Top 25 among Publics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .44 Private Universities Ranking in Top 26–50 among Privates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .46 Public Universities Ranking in Top 26–50 among Publics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .46 Part II: TheCenter Research Universities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .49 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .49 Research . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .50 Private Support and Faculty Quality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .56 Advanced Training and Undergraduate Quality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .62 Change (Federal Research, Endowment, Enrollment) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .68 Institutional Characteristics and TheCenter Measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .74 Student Characteristics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .80 Part III: The Top 200 Institutions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .87 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .87 Total Research Expenditures (1999) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .88 Federal Research Expenditures (1999) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .92 Endowment Assets (2000) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .96 Annual Giving (2000) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .100 National Academy Membership (2000) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .104 Faculty Awards (2000) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .108 Doctorates Awarded (2000) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .112 Postdoctoral Appointees (1999) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .116 SAT Scores (1999) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .120 National Merit and Achievement Scholars (2000) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .124 Source Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .129 Data Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .135 T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 1 Page 2 Introduction The task of building and sustaining an American research university challenges every member of the institution’s extended community. Progress in this permanent quest requires enthusiasm, commitment, talent, and resources, but it also requires reliable comparative data. The task for universities is to improve, not only measured by what they did last year or the year before, but also in comparison to what their counterparts and competitors at other universities have accomplished. Reference points for comparative success serve the utilitarian purpose of measuring progress. The Top American Research Universities annual report charts the comparative performance of institutions, reflecting our conviction that research university success comes from the effective investment in and management of individual institutions. American universities exist in many different bureaucratic arrangements, and public universities in particular often form parts of complex statewide system structures. Nonetheless, the key decisions about faculty and students that produce successful research universities take place primarily at the campus level. For that reason, this publication focuses on the performance of individual campuses, not of systems, and adjusts the data to reflect the performance of each campus within a system. The Top American Research Universities also presents a categorization of research universities into groups based on their performance on nine measures, as described in the text and in the introduction to the tables. Institutions in the top group rank among the top 25 on all nine of the measures; in the second group they rank in the top 25 on eight measures; and so on. This method does not produce a single ranked list, but instead it reflects our observation that the difference separating these top universities is not sufficiently great to justify making a single, rank-ordered list. We think that the very best universities compete at top levels on most everything they do. Others compete well on some measures but not as well on others. TheCenter groups identify clusters of institutions with roughly comparable performance on a variety of measures. In this year’s report, we have extended our coverage to include not only the universities that compete among the top 25, but also those that compete in the range 26–50 on at least one of the nine measures. In this edition, we highlight the national competition among universities in the Top American Research University tables, although we also include the tables for the Top Private and Top Public institutions separately, as in the previous report. This focus on the national rankings recognizes that the competition for faculty and students is primarily a single competition in which both public and private universities participate, regardless of their control or ownership. A university’s private or public ownership (or control) influences some institutional characteristics that bear on its competitiveness within the national context, rather than creating independent competitive contexts. In addition to the expanded tables, this edition of The Top American Research Universities also includes data The task for universities for a variety of institutional characteristics that may be is to improve, not only of interest to many observers. We include information measured by what they on those universities that did last year, but also in we define as major research universities with over comparison with their $20 million in federal research expenditures, and competitors. we include data on the top 200 institutions for the measures used in constructing our categories. Each university, however, exists within a unique context and has different interests in data such as these. For this reason, TheCenter provides all of the data in this publication as well as additional tables of related information on its website [http://thecenter.ufl.edu] in two formats. This publication, including the tables, appears as a .pdf file, available for downloading and printing. All of the published data, as well as some additional tables, appear on the website in Microsoft Excel format suitable for downloading and additional analysis. This gives others the opportunity to analyze the data for their own purposes. The website also includes a variety of other information including an extensive bibliography. T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 3 In the text of The Top American Research Universities, we offer a description of a model for the research university, and we use the data as the basis for the discussion of a variety of issues, especially the patterns of change in federal research expenditures over the past decade. We have discovered that the audience for these materials is much wider than we had anticipated, including academic experts, students, public policy administrators, legislators, trustees, alumni, and international scholars and observers. Some of our comments, reflecting the work of many scholars of American higher education, will appear obvious to the experts, although less familiar to those outside the university. In developing this second edition of The Top American Research Universities, we benefited greatly from many suggestions from our colleagues, but Page 4 special thanks go to the members of our Advisory Board, whom we list on page 147. Their observations, suggestions, and critique have helped us immeasurably. The work reflected in this publication draws on the exceptional support of Ms. Lynne Collis, who manages TheCenter’s administrative services. Without her expertise, dedication, and initiative, this publication would not have appeared. The authors also thank Mr. Gregory A. Harris for his excellent contributions to this project and Ms. Anney Doucette for her careful work with many aspects of the data collection and verification. The Top American Research Universities is a project made possible through the generosity of Mr. Lewis M. Schott in establishing The Lombardi Program on Measuring University Performance. The authors greatly appreciate his confidence and support. The University The American Research University: A Perspective American Higher Education and the Research University Any effort to summarize American higher education struggles with the large variety of missions, structures, and characteristics represented by the over 4,700 institutions offering some form of postsecondary education. Community colleges, trade schools, denominational colleges, liberal arts institutions, small and large state colleges and universities, elite private colleges and universities, and medical institutions all inhabit overlapping parts of the same educational space. This diversity of institutions represents one of the great strengths of American post-secondary schooling. Institutions exist to serve virtually any student, whatever their preferences, needs, values, and abilities. The system lacks formal, structural elegance, but it more than compensates with its comprehensive scope and its remarkable resilience and dynamism. This lack of formal structure poses a major challenge for those who would analyze, categorize, and evaluate these institutions, because few fit into neat categories suitable for data collection and comparative analysis. Institutions as different as community colleges, research universities, and elite liberal arts colleges teach students a relatively standardized curriculum for the first two years. All undergraduate institutions, from large comprehensive state-supported universities to small privately endowed sectarian colleges, compete for college-bound high school graduates. Although these colleges and universities teach students within the context of a four-year undergraduate curriculum leading to a bachelor’s degree, they nonetheless differ substantially in size, characteristics of student populations, and overall institutional mission. Nationally competitive research takes place at approximately the same scale whether in public institutions with as many as 50,000 students or in small private universities with less than 1,000. No effort to understand these institutions on a single scale can hope to succeed. The overlapping missions, diverse governance mechanisms, and multiple sources of funding tend to obscure the highly competitive behavior of American higher education. Institutions compete with each other for funding, students, faculty, and recognition. The nature of this competition, more than the specific characteristics of the institutions themselves, defines groups of institutions: liberal arts colleges compete primarily with other liberal arts colleges, comprehensive state institutions compete with others like themselves, research institutions compete with other research universities. Institutions also compete across categories, not only within them. Community colleges and comprehensive state universities often compete for the same students within a defined geographic area. All public institutions in a given state compete with each other for tax-based support. Prestigious public and private universities compete with small elite liberal arts colleges for top students. Some forms of competition, however, define institutions sufficiently to create a category of analytical interest. Research provides a defining characteristic for a The overlapping missions, set of institutions whose performance in many areas diverse governance, and of academic life sets the multiple sources of standards for most of American higher education. funding tend to obscure The definition of a research university for the the highly competitive purposes of this report behavior of American involves two primary characteristics. higher education. • First, these universities compete successfully for federal research funds. Major research institutions spend at least $20 million a year from these sources, while other research institutions spend less. • Second, research universities are regionally accredited institutions whose academic programs award accredited academic degrees. The following figures provide a perspective on this group of institutions. Of the 1,950 non- T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 5 Non-proprietary Institutions Offering BA/BS Degrees (N=1,950) Institutions with Any Federal Research in 1990–99 (N=617) Institutions with Over $20M Federal Research in FY 1999 (N=154) 48 604 247 106 370 1346 Private proprietary postsecondary institutions that offer at least a bachelor’s degree, some 617 reported expenditures from federal sources on research in at least one year during the period 1990–1999. Within this group of institutions that compete for federally sponsored research, only 154 major research universities spent over $20 million on research from federal sources in fiscal year 1999. The Four Research Groups 250 Private (N=247) Public (N=370) Number of Universities 200 134 150 48 100 41 106 73 50 0 24 87 104 Over $20M $5–20M $1–5M Under $1M (N=154) (N=97) (N=128) (N=238) 1999 Federal Research These 154 institutions account for 91% of annual federal research expenditures. The other 463 universities, taken together, account for the other 9% of the total, and our report divides this larger group into three additional categories for some analysis based on the institution’s 1999 federal expenditures. TheCenter has an interest in all research universities and provides data online for all categories of federal research spending [http://thecenter.ufl.edu]. However, this report continues to focus primarily on Page 6 Public those institutions with over $20 million in federal research expenditures, as in the previous Top American Research Universities report issued in 2000. The highly evolved and complex American research universities in this top category share many things in common, but they differ significantly in size, structure, organization, and finance. Some have student populations as large as 30,000 to 50,000, while others have fewer than 1,000 students. Some have a majority of their students in undergraduate programs, others have a majority of graduate and professional students, and a few have no undergraduates at all. Research universities operate with significantly different formal organizational structures. Some operate as private, not-for-profit corporations and display clearly defined organizations governed by Federal Research Market Share by Research Group Over $20M 91% $5–20M 6.7% $1–5M 1.9% 9% Total Under $1M 0.4% The Research University self-perpetuating boards. Others operate as public entities under state constitutional or legislative provision with ownership or control assigned to boards of trustees or regents. These boards are selected, appointed, or elected in accord with differing criteria. Some public research universities may share a governing board with other institutions, only some of which may emphasize research. Public research universities also have complex relationships that link them directly to state legislatures and statewide coordinating commissions. On occasion, they have both local and statewide governing boards. These research universities do many things in addition to research, further complicating an analysis of their research performance. As educational institutions, research universities can sustain any number of academic specialties, support a wide array of professional schools, engage in extensive off-campus educational activities in continuing professional education, and perform services for public and private constituencies. Individual universities combine these functions in many different ways, ensuring that no two universities will have identical missions. For all of their complexity, American research universities serve as primary institutions for advancing knowledge in virtually all fields of human activity, from the arts and humanities through the social and behavioral sciences and from the professions to the mathematical, physical, and biological sciences. No university cultivates research in all areas of human inquiry, but there is at least one university with a research program in almost every area of knowledge. The strength of the American research university results from a combination of reinforcing elements. For most institutions, the standard mission includes the education of undergraduate students to become useful and productive citizens in what are traditionally four- or five-year programs; the preparation of graduates in the professions of education, law, medicine, business, engineering, or journalism; and the training of advanced students in Ph.D. programs in a number of specialized fields. Research universities in particular emphasize intensive and extensive research programs in many academic and professional areas. Local, state, and national agencies, recognizing the high social and economic value of these institutions, provide significant tax-based assistance to private and public universities through research grants, facilities funding, financial aid for students at all levels. In return, the research university generally implements its obligation to the public by producing educated and useful citizens, transferring academic research results into products and services that enhance national prosperity and defense, and engaging the university in a wide range of public service work. Although there is great variation in the methods and techniques, in the mix and balance, and in the success of American research universities in delivering this combination of functions, almost every institution participates in most aspects of this combined activity. Quality Engines: The American Research University Prototype Even though these institutions demonstrate a bewildering variety in the details of their organization, all of them express a common research university prototype. This prototype models the behavior American research of research universities as organizations, even if, like universities serve as all synthetic constructs, it does not represent the operaprimary institutions tions of any particular instifor advancing knowledge tution in detail. The model presented here in virtually all fields views research universities as organizations with two of human activity. related but relatively independent structures. • The first is an academic core, composed of a group of faculty guilds that have primary responsibility for the academic content and quality of the enterprise. • The second is an administrative shell, responsible for the acquisition and distribution of resources and for the management of the enterprises that support the faculty guilds. The Academic Core: Faculty guilds are the most important part of the university because they define T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 7 and create the university’s academic substance. The guilds enable the university’s many other functions related to teaching and research. Disciplinary considerations define guilds such as chemistry, history, physics, psychology, philosophy, medicine, and law. Moreover, within the university, each Faculty guilds are the faculty guild serves as the local branch of a national most important part guild of the same specialty. For example, all of the profesof the university sors in a university history because they define the department belong to the same national guild, even university’s academic though the local university employs them. The national substance and maintain guild establishes the intellectual standards for their work; its quality. the local university deals with their employment and work assignments. The same holds true for chemists, psychologists, and the members of other guilds. Each guild defines itself in terms of the intellectual methodology that its members apply to their field of study. Historians, for example, have a methodology for the use of historical evidence in the development of explanations about past events. The guild’s definition of standards based on these methods and the evaluation of quality based on the standards are what define the guild’s responsibility. Members of the guild must meet these academic and methodological standards, or the guild will not recognize the validity of their work. As has been the case for all guilds since medieval times, the methodological standards guarantee that the members’ products meet guild criteria. If a guild-certified historian writes a biography of Simón Bolívar, for example, we can have confidence that the interpretation presented uses documents and evidence in accord with the history guild’s standards of accuracy and reliability. The guild does not guarantee the correctness of the resulting interpretation, only that the guild-certified historian used appropriate methodology properly in ways that permit other expert members of the guild to review and validate that work. Page 8 The same is true in science, which perhaps offers a better illustration. Scientists have precise methodologies, both for doing their work and for validating its results. When physicists, for example, present the results of their work, most people lack the expertise to evaluate the scientific validity of the process used to arrive at the announced result. Instead, the public relies on a validation by the physics guild before accepting the result as a reliable scientific finding. Each guild has its own process for validating the work done by its members and for reviewing results presented by aspirants for membership or advancement in the guild. All guilds, however, rely on a variation of the peer review system that mobilizes the talents of expert guild members to validate the work of other guild members. This process often involves experts replicating the experiments and a peer review of results before presentation to the public through publication. Whatever the process, however, the guild sets and enforces the standards for the field to ensure the quality of guild-certified results. The analytical methodology, more than the subject matter studied, distinguishes one guild from another. For example, although historians and sociologists study similar phenomena (revolution, poverty, social change), they employ significantly different methodologies, and these differences separate the sociologists’ guild from the historians’ guild. The expanding range of knowledge constantly produces new information and suggests new explanations. These, in turn, often require new methodologies. Over time, new guilds emerge with definable methodologies that serve to advance understanding. In other cases, efforts to create new guilds do not succeed because no coherent, intellectually sound, and distinct methodology emerges. The guild does not pass judgment primarily on whether a scholar’s idea is right or wrong, but rather it ensures that scholarly ideas receive rigorous analysis and proof regardless of the political or personal interests that may surround them. Scientists may believe that they have found the key to eternal life, but public acceptance of this result requires Quality Engines validation by other members of the appropriate science guilds through a critical review according to applicable methodological standards. The guilds also define the university’s undergraduate curriculum in a negotiated conversation with other guilds. This negotiation establishes the content and delivery of knowledge contained in the traditional frame of four- or five-year undergraduate degree programs. Each component of this degree reflects guild-certified knowledge. Doctoral and other advanced degree programs belong exclusively to the guilds. Finally, the guild controls the acquisition, promotion, tenure, and retention of faculty. Although other actors in the university (administrators, union officials, students, and others) influence this process in various ways, the guild holds primary responsibility for the quality of the faculty. Because their own members hire and retain their successors, guilds behave as self-replicating organizations. If the guilds replicate themselves at the same quality level, the university overall will maintain its current level of quality. If they replace themselves at a lower level, the university declines, and if they hire their replacements at a higher level of quality, the university improves. Research universities pay close attention to guild management of faculty talent, because they know that the university’s quality and productivity depend on the faculty. A diagram of the core structure of the model research university would show a number of guilds, each separate from the others, linked by their common participation in the instructional enterprise and by their common concern for the support and promotion of research. They would appear as separate entities because the members of one guild cannot generally participate in the work of another except as guests or in jointly owned interdisciplinary projects. Members of one guild may not normally transfer their academic standing directly to another guild without a complete review of their qualifications by the other guild. The guilds would also appear as separate entities to emphasize that they belong intellectually more to their national guild than to their local university. This feature of guild behavior requires some discussion. The national guild sets the same methodological standards for determining the quality and reliability of its products everywhere. Local guilds apply these same methodological standards, whether they operate in New York or Texas, Minnesota or California. However, the level of productivity and quality required for membership by each local guild will vary from university to university. In major research universities, as an example, the local history guilds will require new members to possess not only a Ph.D. with a dissertation completed and approved according to the standards of the guild, but also a record of publication in significant peer-reviewed journals and the promise of a major scholarly book. For permanent status within The university’s these high-quality local guilds, historians will academic standing is the publish at least two major peer-reviewed books. At aggregate result of the a comprehensive state universuccess of the guilds in sity, the level of research quality and productivity the recruitment and expected by the local history guild for permanent status retention of faculty. will include perhaps only the completion of a Ph.D. and the publication of one or two peer-reviewed articles. A university’s quality and competitiveness depend on the quality and competitiveness of its faculty, and the local guild sets the level of performance for new and continuing faculty members. The university’s academic standing, then, is the aggregate result of the success of each of these local guilds in the recruitment and retention of faculty. This model of guild behavior applies to competitive research universities and sets the standards for almost all other colleges and universities. The Administrative Shell: The second structure within the American research university is the administrative shell. Most observers see the shell when they first encounter the university. The shell contains a traditional corporate structure: hierarchical and orderly, with a chain of command as well as the other accouterments of modern corporate America. It provides the formal, legal governance T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 9 mechanism of the university, including a board of trustees or regents, a president, and vice presidents, deans, other administrators, and members of faculty senates who carry out corporate line and staff functions on behalf of the university and manage governance as well as administrative issues. To most people, this is the university’s management. In one sense, this is true. The board owns the university. The president is legally responsible for the institution’s management. The vice The criteria for presidents and deans report through an administrative distributing money create hierarchy. The faculty senate approves new degrees and much stronger incentives curricular changes. for guild behavior than At the same time, the people in the shell do not do strategic plans or actually do the work that makes the university valuable. mission statements. That work takes place primarily in the guilds or under guild supervision. The shell mobilizes and distributes resources that support the work of the guilds, and it protects the guilds from harmful external forces. The shell manages the interactions between guilds. Most importantly, the shell manages the university’s money and creates the incentives that motivate guild behavior. Participants in the administrative shell typically demonstrate a fondness for public displays of institutional homogeneity, as expressed in the form of mission statements, strategic plans, and the like. These high-minded products generally have minor impact on the guilds and their work — unless the shell administrators match these plans with the incentives created by the distribution of money. The criteria for distributing money create much stronger incentives for guild behavior than do strategic plans and mission statements articulated by institutional leaders. Deans and department chairs occupy a special intermediate role between the functions of the shell and those of the core guilds. While deans, and chairs to a somewhat lesser extent, serve as administrative officers in the formal organization of the university, they serve more as guild representatives to the shell Page 10 than as administrative managers of the core. Deans receive their appointments from vice presidents and presidents, and they recognize their responsibility to these shell officers. Deans also know that their success depends on their ability to earn and retain the respect and support of their fellow guild members and to successfully represent guild interests in the competition for resources managed by the shell organization. Department and program chairs respond even more closely to the interests of their guild colleagues than do deans. We might think of deans and chairs as “guild masters,” for they manage the operation of the guilds both on behalf of the guild members and on behalf of the shell organization. In this model, it is important to focus on institutional purpose. Some might say that the research university produces students, research products, economic development, and public service. While the university does produce these things, the delivery of goods and services to society is actually a secondary benefit from the university’s primary pursuit of internal quality, as represented by research and students. Quality Engines: Research universities, in our view, exist to accumulate the highest level and the greatest amount of internal academic quality possible. The goal is to gather inside the university the most research-productive faculty, the brightest students, and the highest-quality academic and cultural environment achievable. Although the research university delivers a wide variety of products to external constituencies, such as graduates, technology, economic development, and public service, its primary focus is on the creation of internal quality. This is why we call research universities “quality engines.” In pursuing the goal of maximum internal quality, the research university will almost automatically graduate its students, promote economic development, and serve the public interest. However, the production of these goods and services does not drive university success, although it may motivate others to help the institution to succeed. The model clearly illustrates a relationship between the academic core of guilds and the university’s shell. The shell’s primary responsibility is to Quality Engines find the money needed to compete effectively for the best faculty (including all of the subsidies for their research) and for the best students (including all of the amenities and academic and educational enhancements that attract them). The shell organizes structures and systems to raise private endowments and gifts, to lobby for public funds, to compete for federal dollars, to seek foundation revenue, and to create a hospitable and supportive academic and cultural environment. The shell raises this money and creates this environment so that the guilds succeed in recruiting and retaining quality faculty, in subsidizing research, and in promoting similar activities that create internal quality. Shell participants often take a more direct role in the recruitment and retention of undergraduate students, in whom the guild has less of a direct interest. The interactions between the guilds and the shell, and also between the shell and the external environment, are much more complex and more closely interrelated than presented here. Nonetheless, the model of quality engines focuses our attention on the research university’s revenue-seeking behavior in support of the guild’s success and by extension the institution’s success in the competition for quality. The model sees the university as an enterprise that is its own primary customer. On the surface, this appears a bit contradictory, since the revenue that supports the university comes from outside the institution and the institution organizes itself to capture relentlessly as much revenue from all of these sources as possible. Most observers would assume that the university sells a product or service directly to those who provide it with money. While the university does provide value to those who pay, the process that it uses to provide the value and the mechanisms for payment dilute much of the relationship between buyer and seller that characterizes transactions in the for-profit world. For example, research universities sell the talent of their research faculty and staff to the federal government to do research that is in the national interest. At the same time, universities also purchase access to (and a competitive advantage in) the federal competition for grants through subsidies of research facilities and talent. The universities compete against each other for federal grants, but they also invest their internal funds heavily for the opportunity to compete. The funds that universities use to subsidize the competition for federal research The university come from annual giving, earnings on endowment, maximizes its revenue state agencies, returns on to purchase quality patents and licenses, internal savings, and other research, quality surplus-generating activities of the institution. students, quality Instead of seeing the university as a producer of goods faculty, and a quality and services for an external academic environment. competitive marketplace, we can think of the university as a consumer of the quality that it purchases from the external marketplace. In this view, the university maximizes its revenue from all sources to purchase quality research, quality students, quality faculty, and a quality academic environment. It then uses the existence of this quality environment to attract additional external investors who buy access to the environment and contribute to its creation rather than purchasing ownership of any particular university product. The goal of research universities, then, is to accumulate the highest level and the largest amount of quality it can through the competitive purchase of scarce quality elements. Whether the institution is an elite private institution with a $14 billion endowment and $266 million of federally funded research or a public institution just barely over the $20 million level of federal research with an endowment of only $15 million, they behave in remarkably similar ways. The details of the revenue-seeking behavior of individual universities vary depending on circumstances, history, opportunities, and private or public control. TheCenter’s annual reports track the performance of research universities as they pursue the maximum accumulation of research and undergraduate student quality. T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 11 The Competitive Context for Research Universities The research university’s essential elements are scarce. Universities and their people live in an environment of competition for everything: outstanding students, good grades, faculty positions, promotion and tenure, publication opportunities, grants, research and teaching space, and resources to support academic specialties are a few examples. The most important competition for faculty begins with the hiring process, when one open position attracts many applicants but the applicant pool contains only a few top candidates. Potential faculty members compete with each other to appear in the top group of aspiring research faculty, and universities compete with each other to purchase the services of the individuals in the top group. Availability of Research and Teaching Talent: The discussion of the process for recruiting, promoting, tenuring, and retaining faculty is long, and we will not engage it fully here. For our purposes in charting the performance of research universities, a critical distinction about this competition for the best faculty requires emphasis. Research university competition for faculty is about research, not about teaching. Much confusion and rhetoric attaches to this view, as observers of university life argue about the relative merits of teachResearch talent and ing and research. For our purposes, this argument is productivity are much beside the point. The issue less available and much is not whether teaching or research has more intrinsic less predictable than is value, but whether teaching talent is more plentiful teaching talent. than research talent. Research talent and productivity is much less available and much less predictable than teaching talent, and this difference determines the university’s focus on research rather than teaching in the acquisition and management of faculty. Although teaching requires skill, knowledge, creativity, and commitment, this is not the issue. The issue is that almost all faculty with the basic credentials for a research university appointment Page 12 (a Ph.D. or its equivalent and a reasonable record of scholarly accomplishment) will teach well. The likelihood is high that a university, in hiring promising research faculty members, will also acquire excellent teachers. Like teaching, research also requires skill, knowledge, creativity, and commitment, but research talent is scarce. The guilds cannot predict with high levels of confidence which of the most promising research graduates of the best doctoral programs in the country will sustain a high level of nationally competitive research productivity over a working career. By selecting and reviewing credentials carefully, the guild can improve its chances of hiring and retaining people who will indeed perform as researchers throughout their careers, but the risk nonetheless remains substantial. As time goes on, even with the most careful screening, the proportion of a cohort of promising faculty who remain productive in research will decline. A few will not produce nationally competitive research at all; many will produce well for six to eight years and then cease to compete at national levels. Others will create sustained and productive research programs and will maintain their vitality and competitiveness over a career of thirty or more years. By contrast, in any given cohort of faculty hired by a research university, all but a very few will teach effectively, and many will teach superbly for the thirty or more years of their careers. From a management perspective, this creates a problem, because the labor force required for universities to succeed in the national research competition is relatively inflexible. Once the long six-year period of probation ends, faculty become permanent university employees. Tenure confers this security of employment and is the structure that creates an inflexible labor force, but it is also a requirement for a successful university research enterprise. The topic of tenure is complex and has an extensive and often polemical literature. Suffice it to say here that university research that extends human knowledge does not prosper where the investigator’s livelihood is dependent on evaluations of short-term success. The pursuit of short-term research results often leads people to work on the things they already The Competitive Context know well rather than on the things they do not know. The pursuit of new knowledge entails a substantial risk of being wrong (scholars can only be right all of the time if they already know the answers to the questions they ask). The employment security of tenure is a necessary requirement to encourage this risky exploration of the unknown, and it represents a cost in the university’s support of research. Universities compete with each other by paying a premium in the faculty marketplace for successful research faculty at various stages in their careers because such individuals are scarce. Universities pay almost no premium for successful teaching faculty at any stage in their careers because such individuals are abundant. Indeed, the emergence of a lively market in inexpensive adjunct and part-time teaching talent indicates a negative premium for teaching experience. The limited availability of research talent and the competition to acquire this talent explain why the conversation about mobilizing resources for institutional quality focuses primarily on the competition for and support of research faculty. Supporting Research Competition: This model of research universities as quality engines highlights the close relationship between competitive success and money. Money makes it possible for the institutions to compete for the scarce talent of research faculty and to support all of the elements of plant, equipment, personnel, and university environment that they require. University people see themselves as pursuing a higher mission and do not like to think of themselves as part of enterprises that generate and spend revenue. Yet in no university does the higher mission prosper without the investment of money in people, plant, and equipment. The centrality of money to this competition affects every single program, whether it is fine arts and music or physics and chemistry. The art department needs studio space and materials; the music school needs rehearsal space, instruments, and recording equipment. The physics and chemistry departments require laboratory space and scientific instruments. The best faculty in every guild want nationally competitive salaries, and the best students want nationally competitive undergraduate programs and financial aid packages. The quality engine’s success depends in the first instance on its ability to generate money. All things being equal, the more money the university can invest effectively in the competition for quality, the better it will become. Research university shells, as predicted by our model, organize the mechanisms for maximizing revenue. The competition among All things being equal, universities for people and resources is fierce. If a the more money the research project will take university can invest five years to develop, the university that starts first effectively in the will finish first. The university that gets the three competition for quality, best faculty in the world in the better it will become. a particular field will have a competitive edge. While research faculty move from institution to institution for higher salaries and better research support, they do not move every year. If the faculty with the critical talent needed for a research project moved last year, they will not likely move this year. The advantage in the competition goes to those who have the money today to buy the services of talented people and the equipment and resources needed. What matters most for the research university is not its total assets or the aggregate value of its endowment, buildings, and equipment. Rather, what matters most is the cash generated by these assets and other activities, which the university can immediately spend to compete. Competitive university research operates at the outside edges of human knowledge, and small differences in talent and ability often make big differences in research success. If a university fails to recruit the top quantum physicists for its project, it will find itself disadvantaged in competing against the university that has those top physicists. The disadvantage will rapidly become serious as the competing university moves quickly ahead in the process of discovery. T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 13 Research is also a high-risk business, and institutions find it difficult to predict exactly which research investment will produce the most competitive result in the medium term of five to ten years. The larger the cash flow that a university can mobilize to invest in different research initiatives, the greater the chance that it will have successful results, and the better its ability to withstand failures. Individual scientific research programs may have a lifespan of ten years, and in that time the instituUniversities frequently tion will invest many millions from its own resources (in use decision mechanisms addition to whatever it can that rely primarily on win in grants and external support) for salaries, space, traditions, politics, or equipment, and support personnel. If it spends personal preferences that its revenue well, the university will see returns on this limit the effective use of investment in the form of rational criteria. discoveries, publications, grants, contracts, and scholarly reputation. If it invests ineffectively, it will see its quality decline despite that investment. Universities encounter significant challenges in managing the institution’s investment choices. Universities and their faculty engage in many activities, produce many things, and have multiple constituencies. Every activity can benefit from the investment of additional dollars, and all activities have internal and external support groups that argue for additional investment in their preferred activity. Almost all of these activities reflect quality programs. As the model would predict, the process for making investment decisions in a university is complex. This is because the guilds have their own interests centered on guild advancement, and the shell often lacks the technical and political support to make effective investment choices. Deans and chairs represent not the interests of the university but those of the guilds or collections of guilds under their administration. Pressures from both the academic core and the external constituencies of revenue Page 14 providers, combined with often remarkably poor management data, inhibit the effective use of resources to build competitive quality. Universities frequently use decision mechanisms that reflect the complicated relationships of their many constituencies and that rely primarily on traditions, politics, or personal preferences. These common mechanisms limit the effective use of the rational criteria that will guide the institution to identify the optimal choice for acquiring internal quality. When a university has large amounts of discretionary revenue, it can often afford ineffective systems and nonetheless remain competitive. However, universities with fewer resources will find that these ineffective decision methods inhibit their efforts to improve. Decisions about spending money have a disproportionate impact on research because research is a money-losing proposition with significant multiplier effects. Universities must generate as much revenue as possible so that they can buy as much quality research as possible. Each investment of internal funds creates the opportunity to acquire additional external funds in support of research. Good investments create large multipliers and research grows rapidly; poor investments have small multipliers and produce much slower growth. Research, even though it can serve as a multiplier, creates an expense, not a surplus. Although externally funded grants and contracts are large items in any research university’s revenue stream, they represent the multiplier effect of the additional university funds that these projects always require to pay their full cost. Some of these required payments from internal resources appear explicitly: for example, underpayment for indirect costs is a characteristic of federal, state, and especially foundation sponsored projects. Although the effective recovery of indirect costs varies from institution to institution, no university recovers the full audited costs of research. The difference between the audited and the reimbursed expenses is a cost to the university of the successful competition for grant-funded research projects. Universities subsidize research in many other ways. Released time from teaching for faculty who The Competitive Context do research in the humanities, social sciences, arts, and professions (fields with fewer substantial external grants) is a cost of research for the university. Funded grants from federal and other agencies often require an explicit university payment from internal funds, called “cost sharing,” as a condition for acquiring the grant. The competition for quality human resources impels universities to fund endowed positions for research faculty, the cost of which they rarely charge in full to research grants. Institutions also subsidize graduate students through stipends both to attract the quality research faculty who teach them and to provide talented labor for research projects. The direct competition for research faculty often involves even larger subsidies. When a university succeeds in attracting a highly productive faculty member in the sciences from another institution, for example, the recruitment package usually includes many expenses beyond the individual’s increased salary and benefits. The university will pay for the cost of moving the scientist’s laboratory to the new university, the cost of laboratory renovations and set up, the cost of new equipment to replace equipment belonging to the prior institution. It will also pay to acquire the newly hired faculty member’s students and assistants, costs that include moving them and setting up their research space. Universities do this because the newly acquired faculty member’s team will bring larger and more significant research grants to the university, thereby increasing institutional quality. The institution also knows that it will never recover most of these relocation costs. Instead, the increased research grants and contracts brought by the newly acquired faculty member will require additional subsidies. The gain is in the acquisition of internal quality for the institution, thus improving the multiplier of university investments in research, but the university must first generate the revenue that it needs to invest in this quality. As the quality engine model shows, university success comes from the ability to spend wisely an ever-increasing revenue stream. For a research university, spending it well means increasing research productivity by acquiring the best faculty and programs, competing successfully for the most prestigious grants, and ultimately, publishing the most significant advances in the arts, humanities, social sciences, professions, and sciences. Universities and colleges The Undergraduate Competition: Competition sell undergraduate among research universities also includes an aggressive education primarily as effort in the teaching enteran experienced process prise. While the research competition focuses on the rather than as a acquisition of scarce faculty research talent, undergradupurchased product. ate programs compete for the limited number of top-quality students. The perceived quality of a university’s undergraduate program depends in considerable measure on the quality of its student body. The better the quality of students that the university can recruit, the better the quality of undergraduate program it will have. This assumption about undergraduate quality is an important reality of the university marketplace. The undergraduate competition focuses primarily on non-academic issues that parents and students assume are relevant to the educational experience. This is an interesting phenomenon because undergraduate education is ostensibly about acquiring the defined body of knowledge that the degree certifies. If we decompose undergraduate education into its component parts, however, we find that the formal academic curriculum follows a relatively standard form at most universities and resembles a commodity product. This is true because accreditation agencies, financial aid organizations, public regulatory agencies, legislatures, and consumers of undergraduate education prefer a relatively standardized curriculum. Over time, the formal content of the undergraduate degree has tended towards a high degree of standard content from one university to another. While the curriculum may vary in terms of electives and the degree of emphasis placed on science, humanities, ethics, or religion, the basic content of a four- or five-year bachelor’s degree has become T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 15 almost a commodity product, even if the way it is delivered and the faculty who deliver it vary significantly from institution to institution. In addition, even though the quality of the undergraduate content and the quality of the teaching may differ from institution to institution, the consumers generally cannot easily recognize these differences directly. Undergraduate consumers do not constitute repeat buyers in the marketplace for the most part. The differences in quality from institution to institution, while perhaps significant in some instances, have no obvious external measure. Instead, consumers look for indirect measures of presumed academic quality. As a result, universities tend to compete for students based more on the quality of the experience that students will receive at the university while pursuing the standard curricular structure, rather than on highly differentiated content within the curriculum. Without clear indicators Universities and colleges sell undergraduate education of undergraduate primarily as an experienced process rather than as a purquality, consumers chased product. They issue take the quality of a token of successful participation in that process — the students as a signal degree or diploma — but the degree certifies participation of quality content. that meets relatively generic standards and does not necessarily guarantee a particular result or a defined level of competence. Different participants will take away different results from the experience, even though they all receive the same degree. Universities and colleges imply that the degree represents a product containing a measurable and standard amount of education or knowledge. Efforts to measure this learning in some clear and reliable way have so far failed to establish a definition of the content of a standard undergraduate degree. The apparent commodity characteristic of the content and the difficulty of measuring the result of the process lead universities to compete for students based on the quality and variety of experiences and opportunities that the process provides. Page 16 As is the case with all providers of name-brand commodities, universities invest heavily in differentiating the presentation and the context of their undergraduate process to compete for quality students. The differentiation involves such things as smaller classes, enhanced extracurricular activities, and elaborate entertainment for participants through sports, art, music, theater, and similar amenities. Universities enrich the basic commodity content with learning experiences such as overseas campuses, honors programs, off-campus fieldwork, internships, and individualized study. Universities offer a wide range of experiences to accompany the commodity content by providing activities such as leadership opportunities in clubs and student government. They offer special non-academic services such as psychological counseling and travel opportunities, as well as elaborate recreation, intramural sports, and fitness programs. Success in this competition comes from attracting a high-quality student population to the campus. This is a self-reinforcing phenomenon. Without clear and direct indicators of quality, consumers take the quality of enrolled students as one of the most important signals of quality content. The high quality of existing students attracts high-quality applicants, and from this group the university can select an even higher-quality student body. All of this activity in pursuit of the quality student costs money. Enhanced facilities consume revenue. High-quality students expect preferential treatment in the form of tuition discounts and other financial aid considerations. In large, public universities with low tuition, a tuition discount is not a major benefit, but special housing, small classes for honors students, and special extracurricular opportunities all cost money and help to attract the best students. Indeed, the competitiveness of the honors programs at public institutions is such that their admissions standards are often higher than those at most elite private colleges (and of course much higher than the general admission standards of the public institution itself). The undergraduate financial model that supports this competition varies by institutional control. The Competitive Context Private institutions use substantial subsidies drawn from endowment income and annual gifts to support the tuition discounts that attract the best students. This limits the size of the student body that they can support. Public universities, with taxsupported payments for instruction, often respond to the political process and state funding systems when setting enrollments. Public institutions use their discretionary dollars to create special programs and enrich the educational experience that they offer to the most desirable students. The undergraduate financial system depends less on the sale of admission to students and more on the acquisition of funds from multiple sources to support the experience of students. Many who do not participate directly in undergraduate education nonetheless pay for its success. Some funding comes by virtue of social policies such as state and federal payments for student financial aid. Alumni and other private individuals contribute to scholarships and programs for undergraduates because they value a continuing identification with the undergraduate experience. Others support quality undergraduate programs through bequests, endowments, and capital gifts that secure the immortality of permanent recognition. The motives for these purchasers of undergraduate quality are many, but each purchase recognizes value in the process, although many of those who contribute to the cost of undergraduate education (state and federal legislators and private donors in particular) do not actually receive a direct benefit. Colleges and universities invest heavily in enhancements to the undergraduate experience, because they know that the quality of students and of student life attracts other students and signals the overall quality of the institution to donors, alumni, faculty, legislators, and others. For the same reasons, colleges and universities invest in elegant campuses, ivy-covered buildings, student recreation facilities, cultural entertainment programs, alumni halls, intercollegiate sports, and other non-academic features of college life. The techniques used to fund the endless additions to the undergraduate process and to enhance the physical and experiential elements of college life vary among institutions, but the drive to generate revenue for investment in this competition for high-quality students is visible in all institutional types. The Combination of Undergraduate and Research Competition: High-quality research Research universities, by universities compete directly with the single-function, elite virtue of the complexity undergraduate colleges for the scarce talent of superior stuof their activities, dents. It is no surprise, then, cross-subsidize research to discover that the undergraduate part of the research from teaching and university functions in ways that mimic the elite college. teaching from research. However, where the elite college emphasizes the benefits of a smaller size, the research universities tend to emphasize the benefits of their nationally preeminent research faculty and the breadth of their offerings. In this competition for quality undergraduates, the research university has some advantages. Research universities, by virtue of the complexity of their activities, find ways to cross-subsidize research from teaching, and teaching from research. The most obvious example involves the physical plant. Facilities that the university builds for research often support some forms of teaching as well, either through laboratory use or by housing faculty who teach. Similarly, facilities constructed in support of teaching also house faculty who conduct research. Libraries serve both teaching and research, but the support of a research program allows a much larger and richer library for undergraduates than the university could afford based on its undergraduate program alone. At the same time, in public universities, tax-generated funding for libraries often follows formulas based on enrollment, and the existence of a larger undergraduate population may make possible a richer research library than the university could afford on the basis of its research activity alone. Computing resources, like libraries, often have a scale in support of teaching and research that they could not reach based on one or the other alone. The most important shared element, of course, is the faculty. Research universities can have a larger T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 17 faculty than they could justify by the teaching mission alone, because the institution subsidizes a portion of faculty time for research purposes and competes for research dollars that sustain additional parts of the faculty’s costs. The university will not necessarily have more faculty members teaching smaller classes. Instead, the students will have the opportunity to engage a wider range of high-quality research faculty talent. The key distinction is the word “opportunity.” In the competition that surrounds the standard content of undergraduate education, the opportunity for participation is often just as important as a student actually engaging research faculty. Many students do not care to engage faculty beyond the minimum requirements, while others anticipate Some institutions avoid that they will engage but do not actually do so. confronting the data, Research faculty may not but those who seek teach many of the large, lower-division undergraduate improvement know that courses, but they frequently teach upper-division courses they must monitor the for majors. As a result, students in general may not have numbers reflecting their many encounters with distincompetitive position. guished research faculty, but they usually will have at least some encounters, thus validating the opportunity for participation. Both the presence of the research enterprise and the high national visibility of such activity enhance the institution’s ability to generate revenue from other sources in support of undergraduate education. Donors, for example, in giving to scholarships and other funds that the university uses to recruit the best undergraduate students, may be responding just as much to the institution’s research reputation as they are to the actual quality of the undergraduate program. Conversely, undergraduate education also supports research. The best research faculty often value their membership in an academic community that includes quality undergraduate programs and student life. They seek an academic environment Page 18 that includes sports facilities, recreation, music, fine arts, and other entertainment and culture brought by the existence of the quality undergraduate experience. All faculty value their membership in a university community that they perceive to be intellectually elite, and the quality of the undergraduates is one of the tokens of elite status that universities use in recruiting stellar faculty. Many research faculty also seek the opportunity to teach talented undergraduates. In some circumstances, the relationship between undergraduate education and research is more direct and revenue-related. In public universities, the undergraduate mission — seen by state agencies as a primary activity — often generates an amount of revenue that exceeds the direct cost of undergraduate education. In such cases, undergraduate students become a profit center, generating revenue above their costs that the university can then reinvest to subsidize quality research. States sometimes fund universities based on formulas that anticipate providing the university with some research support for every undergraduate student enrolled. This reflects the belief that faculty research contributes to the quality of undergraduate education. As mentioned above, states often use formulas based on undergraduate enrollment in funding facilities for infrastructure, library, or computing, thus creating a subsidy for research facilities at the same time. This revenue synergy between teaching and research at public universities offsets their relatively small endowments as compared to their private university competitors. It also helps to explain the relatively large size of undergraduate populations at public research institutions. In a private institution, which lacks publicly funded subsidies for education, the size of the undergraduate population is more a function of the revenue available to subsidize quality students. Increasing the size of the student body usually does not increase available revenue, especially if the university must pay more to educate the students than their discounted tuition can cover. The drive to acquire quality students and research faculty creates a universal imperative: to generate the revenue needed to compete for these scarce but The Competitive Context essential elements. The university, represented by its shell structure, organizes its systems into a revenuegenerating organization on behalf of faculty research and student quality. In this competition, institutions require both the availability of the revenue and its effective investment to produce a top American research university. Measuring Institutional Competitiveness for Research Universities Ranking and Measuring The operation of research universities is a required topic for everyone interested in improving institutional performance. Often, the rhetoric of improvement implies a positive-sum game in which everyone can improve by doing the right thing. In one sense, this is true, for every university can improve its internal operations and enhance its performance as a result. The message of positive-sum improvement, however, implies that the choice of what to improve is a local concern. If every university could improve without regard to other participants in the higher education environment, then improvement relative to others would not be particularly important. The significant question would then be internal: how well does the institution perform on whatever internal agenda it defines? University improvement programs often appear in this format, proposing to enhance some aspect of the local environment as if what happens elsewhere is of minor concern or serves primarily as a source of examples of desirable programs and activities. The advantage of this perspective is that such improvement programs generally have weak mechanisms for determining success or failure, since any change can appear to be beneficial. Its inherent flaw, however, is that it ignores the reality of competition for scarce but essential resources. As the quality engine model shows, quality elements are scarce, and universities acquire them through competition against other institutions. Competition for students, faculty, and research defines the performance of the research university. Some institutions may prefer to avoid confronting the data that describe their success in this competition; however, those who seek improvement know that they must monitor the numbers reflecting their competitive position. Universities and their constituents often focus on process issues rather than on performance. They worry about the process for distributing revenue, for hiring faculty, and for recruiting students. They pay much less attention to the results and especially to the comparative results. However, if the process for distributing revenue to the guilds produces internal harmony and high levels of participation but fails to improve either undergraduate quality or research performance, then it is actually a failed process, regardless of the state of internal harmony. Sustaining undergraduate programs and research at nationally competitive levels of quality and productivity requires constant measurement, close attention to revenues and expenditures, and close faculty and administrative management. A few universities perform at top competitive levels; others compete more effectively in some things and less so in others. TheCenter’s data identify some of the characteristics of the institutions that excel in this national competition. The data in this publication (presented in more detail online) display these characteristics. Institutions are often frustrated by the lack of tools The drive to acquire that are currently available for measuring their success in quality students and the competition for faculty, students, and dollars. In part, research creates a this is the result of the locauniversal imperative: tion of universities within corporate space. As not-forto generate the revenue profit enterprises, they enjoy a self-justifying existence needed to compete for that requires them to provide these scarce but essential only a limited number of validated references to the pubelements. lic. Although universities provide an endless stream of T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 19 reports and surveys to external agencies and governing organAlthough universities izations, these rarely offer the complain bitterly about data necessary for effective management or for reliable the unreliable nature of institutional comparison. Detailed, standardized rankings, they advertise information does exist for a variety of accounting their own success in purposes that are useful for spurious rankings with demonstrating the fulfillment of the institution’s enthusiasm. fiduciary responsibilities, but these data do not usually serve a useful management purpose. Systems for ranking and classifying universities abound, and many of these systems use data that are unreliable or inappropriate for this purpose. Many rankings attempt to capture in one number an aggregate evaluation of the institution’s worth relative to others. No currently available data offer sufficient reliability or coverage to accomplish this task. The widely varying results from year to year of the most popular of these rankings, outlined in a paper published online by TheCenter, offer eloquent testimony to the unreliability of the measures, since colleges and universities in the top categories rarely change their competitive performance significantly from one year to the next. These popular rankings will often move institutions up and down in ways that do not reflect real changes in performance. In addition, universities compete in the marketplace of public opinion based on prestige or reputation, which is often a highly subjective evaluation. Prestige is a form of name-brand recognition derived from historical visibility, from promotional campaigns that project institutional identity, and from the halo effect of real accomplishments. As a result, colleges and universities emphasize what is unique and different in their environment. They collect information that identifies them as unique in a comparative context. Special characteristics demonstrated by institutionally unique data are a hallmark of much university-generated public relations information. Prestige, or reputation, also reflects past behavior and publicity more than current Page 20 performance, and its unreliability severely limits the validity of rankings that use reputation as an indicator. Various national groups publish many rankings of universities, colleges, and programs, and these rankings fill a vacuum created by the inability of universities to agree on standard, validated measures of performance or on common criteria for judging competitiveness. Although many universities complain bitterly about the unreliable nature of the rankings (and they truly are often quite unreliable), these same universities nonetheless advertise their own success in spurious rankings with great enthusiasm. In the competition for the best students and faculty, universities embrace positive rankings in the effort to enhance their reputations. They also use positive rankings from virtually any source to persuade donors and other revenue providers that the institution’s unique and valuable mission deserves a gift or grant or additional state or federal subsidy. The highly publicized but methodologically questionable rankings serve this purpose. They create an illusion of distinction and differentiation, offer a presumably impartial validation of qualities promoted by the institution, and create an opportunity for self-promotion that outsiders find difficult to challenge and that insiders find difficult to resist. Within the many rankings done by organizations with different purposes and using different methodologies, universities can usually find at least one that ranks them highly on some criteria. These rankings, in spite of their visibility, do not help university managers, although they may indeed help the public relations effort. No business, not-for-profit or otherwise, can allow promotional materials alone to serve as accurate measures of its competitive success. To do so is to forfeit the opportunity to improve the university’s performance. Without clear measurement and a commitment to competitive success, universities tend to replicate themselves at the same level (or at slightly declining levels) of performance. Absent institutional commitment, the external competition for the best students and faculty will slowly erode a university’s quality. Beyond the minimal requirements of enrollment Ranking and Measuring and meeting the institution’s steady state financial commitments, nothing in the external environment compels a self-generating research university to become better than it already is. The drive to compete at a high level generally comes from within the institution. For research universities, the risks inherent in unmeasured management are significant. This is because success is so heavily dependent on the institution’s ability to generate the money for effective investment in research and student subsidies. An institution that manages its money poorly loses the opportunity to generate surpluses to invest in research and student quality. An institution that raises too little endowment to generate income or inadequate annual giving to sustain its subsidies, for example, will eventually fail to maintain its market share in the research competition, thus losing its competitive edge in recruiting the best students. An institution that invests without measuring results will waste its resources. In the competition for quality undergraduates and research performance, the total size of the university’s budget does not matter as much as the way that the institution uses its money. If a large institution with a budget in excess of a billion dollars spends large portions of its revenue on activities that are unrelated to research or undergraduate quality, it will have a less competitive research university than a much smaller institution that spends most of its money on research and undergraduate quality. The first requirement for a successful research university is to generate revenue. The second requirement is to spend it well. The detailed and specific methods that universities use internally to make good choices vary from place to place and from time to time, but a number of measures do exist that serve as reasonably reliable indicators of an institution’s competitiveness in the national marketplace. A discussion of these measures appears below. Defining the Competition: Although the quality engine model depicts research universities operating two theoretically separable economies for teaching and research, most institutional accounting systems do not separate the revenue and expenses clearly enough to analyze these economies separately. Rather than trying to identify research or teaching revenue and expenses as separate elements, it is more useful to imagine that the university purchases its undergraduate and research quality by drawing the money from one common fund. This is not true in detail, of course, since most university money is restricted to specific purposes in both private and public institutions. Nonetheless, universities gain more by thinking of all of the revenue as being available for any purpose: money is money. Institutions that first identify the best uses for their revenue (whether in improving the quality of the undergraduate student body or in improving the quality of the research enterprise), before considering various restrictions and limitations created by the providers of the revenue, will make better choices. They will identify the highest and best use of each dollar, and then, if necessary, they can make adjustments, reallocations, or transfers to meet required fund restrictions. By making their choices first, however, many universities find that they can accommodate fund restrictions and still stay on track with their optimal expenditure plan. If the university begins its budget plan by considering the limitations on funds, it will have The first requirement considerable difficulty identifor a successful fying the highest and best uses for the money. research university is The most useful measures of a university’s competitiveto generate revenue. ness mark the institution’s success in securing quality The second requirement research, a quality student is to spend it well. body, and quality faculty. The university with the most research, the highest student quality, and the most distinguished faculty is thus the most competitive. Of course, such measures do not mean that universities with smaller numbers are of less intrinsic value or that their smaller number of research faculty are less distinguished or less productive than the larger number at the more competitive institution. The data only identify which institutions compete most successfully for the largest share of the quality elements that all universities seek. T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 21 These data help to clarify general impressions about university performance. The differences between institutions with similar performance characteristics are not great, which is why TheCenter classifies institutions into groups based on their performance within the top 25 or the top 50 institutions on a variety of measures. More important than the classification of institutions into these groups, the comparable data provided by TheCenter allows universities to measure the effectiveness of their improvement initiatives. Indicators of Competitiveness: Although we cannot measure research university competition directly at the institutional level, a number of comparable indicators exist that, when taken together, give a reasonably good sense of a university’s competitiveness. This publication reports on these indicators, which the 2000 edition of The Top American Research Universities described in detail. In the following summary of each of the measures, we have included a high-median-low graphic that captures the range of performance of private and public research institutions on each measure within each of the four research groups or categories (over $20 million, $5 to $20 million, $1 to $5 million, and under $1 million in federal research expenditures). To reduce the effect of outliers, the high represents the 75th percentile and the low represents the 25th percentile. Briefly, the most important indicator of research competitiveness is the institution’s annual federal research expenditures. This number, reported by Federal Research by Research Group and Control Public 75th Percentile Median 25th Percentile Over $20M $5–$20M $1–$5M Under $1M $180,000 $160,000 1999 Federal Research (x $1,000) Private $140,000 $120,000 $100,000 $87,152 $80,000 $60,000 $55,873 $40,000 $20,000 $11,384 $9,992 $2,361 $0 Page 22 $2,234 $233 $219 the National Science Foundation (NSF), reflects an institution’s research expenditures in the areas of science and engineering from funds awarded by the various programs of the National Institutes of Health (NIH), the National Science Foundation, and other agencies of the federal government, including the departments of Defense and Energy. These dollars, generally distributed through an intensely competitive peer-reviewed process, reflect the active scientific community’s judgment on the competitiveness of the faculty at each institution. An additional value of this measure is that it indicates the effectiveness of the institution in supporting research, for the more money a university spends in support of research, all things being equal, the more research it will get. Of course, if a university spends its money in support of research that does not result in publication or other peerreviewed results, its standing in this competition will not improve. For these reasons, most observers of the competition among American research universities watch the federal research expenditure number as the most reliable single indicator of research competitiveness. NSF also reports the annual federal awards of grants and contracts for research received by each institution, which is a significantly less useful measure. Awards often reflect multi-year commitments; expenditures capture the actual work done on projects during a given year. Awards also include dollars that subsequently flow to other universities under subcontracts. For institutions moving rapidly ahead on a research promotion agenda, the awards number may help to demonstrate their growing success in competing for greater amounts of research funding, but as a comparative measure of current university performance, the expenditure data are more reliable. Universities, both private and public, in addition to the federal expenditures, report expenditures from non-federal sources, including corporations, state governments, and foundation or for-profit research enterprises. These expenditures, more broadly defined than the federal number, include a variety of specially designated state funds that are allocated to institutions within the state for agriculture or other research purposes. Such funding may not be nation- Ranking and Measuring $5–$20M $1–$5M Under $1M 1999 Total Research (x $1,000) $250,000 $200,000 $150,000 $126,001 $114,024 $100,000 $50,000 $15,522 $0 $21,005 $3,294 $3,454 $503 $576 ally competitive. Nonetheless, these expenditures, combined with the federal expenditures, reflect total research activity and provide a useful indicator of research performance, even if the national peer review process does not referee all of the projects included in this number. Most of the non-federal portion of this total research, especially when funded by foundations, requires institutional subsidies as well. Thus, many observers recognize total research expenditures as another useful indicator of research competitiveness. Universities that do not have large portfolios of corporate or agricultural research will argue that the total research measurement puts them at a disadvantage in any comparison. While that may be true, institutions still make many choices in how they will spend their revenue in support of research. Some will take advantage of medical schools; others will leverage their opportunities in agriculture. Some will take advantage of successfully constructed linkages between industry and programs in engineering to generate corporate funding. Others will benefit from alumni who direct large foundations that make research grants. The issue here is not the relative value of the different types of research but rather the strategies and successes of universities in creating the revenue necessary to expand their research portfolios. In making choices about how to compete for external research funding, some universities compete in all sectors of the research market, while others compete only in the parts of the market where they identify a comparative advantage. The federal and Endowment Assets by Research Group and Control Over $20M $5–$20M $1–$5M Under $1M $3,500,000 $3,000,000 2000 Endowment Assets (x $1,000) Over $20M $300,000 total research expenditures capture most of this activity, and together these two serve as useful indicators of competitive research success. In the discussion of changes in research competitiveness included in this edition of The Top American Research Universities, however, we maintain our focus on federal research expenditures. Although it is difficult to derive a valid measure of the total financial resources that are available to a research university, two measures provide some indication of the university’s ability to compete for private funds. Endowment represents the university’s permanent fund that continues to generate income each year. Annual giving includes the total gifts received by the university in the most recent year. While endowment reflects a long history of private giving, as well as the growth of the fund through retained earnings and appreciation, it also serves as $2,500,000 $2,000,000 $1,500,000 $1,278,774 $1,000,000 $500,000 $258,000 $189,547 $60,852 $0 $164,011 $38,636 $160,248 $20,805 Annual Giving by Research Group and Control Over $20M $5–$20M $1–$5M Under $1M $240,000 2000 Annual Giving (x $1,000) Total Research by Research Group and Control T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s $200,000 $160,000 $120,000 $93,629 $80,000 $40,000 $46,712 $33,346 $12,547 $0 $15,112 $7,655 Page 23 $12,137 $3,013 Public 75th Percentile Median National Academy Membership by Research Group and Control 25th Percentile Over $20M $5–$20M $1–$5M Under $1M 45 2000 National Academy Members 40 35 30 25 20 15 13 10 5 5 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 Faculty Awards by Research Group and Control Over $20M $5–$20M $1–$5M The number of doctorates awarded reflects the university’s commitment to advanced study in all fields. Postdoctoral appointees demonstrate the commitment of the institution to subsidizing the cost of advanced training, much of which is in support of research, as well as their success in competing for grants that include postdoctoral support. Finally, as our model indicates, the best research universities spend a significant portion of revenue on the maintenance of high-quality undergraduate programs, and the median SAT score of the entering freshman class serves as an indicator of success in this competition. Graduate student quality would also be a useful indicator, but the data for such an indicator are not available in a form we can use in this project. Under $1M 30 Doctorates Awarded by Research Group and Control 25 20 Over $20M $5–$20M $1–$5M Under $1M 350 15 13 300 7 5 0 1 2 1 1 0 0 an indirect indicator of the annual income available from this source for current competitive expenditures. Annual giving reflects the most recent efforts of the institution in the private marketplace for donations. Data that directly measure faculty quality and productivity at the institutional level are rare, but national figures do exist on the numbers of National Academy memberships and prestigious faculty awards of various kinds. These distinctions, which recognize individual faculty merit in a wide range of scholarly disciplines, serve as useful indicators of an institution’s success in acquiring scarce faculty talent. Taken together, the two measures identify faculty recognized for distinction in the sciences, the humanities and social sciences, as well as most other fields of academic scholarship. Page 24 2000 Doctorates Awarded 10 250 200 186 150 149 100 50 41 28 8 0 0 0 0 Postdoctoral Appointees by Research Group and Control Over $20M $5–$20M $1–$5M Under $1M 450 400 350 1999 Postdoctoral Appointees 2000 Faculty Awards Private 300 250 200 150 206 139 100 50 19 0 10 0 0 0 0 Ranking and Measuring Median SAT Scores by Research Group and Control Over $20M $5–$20M $1–$5M Under $1M 1450 1400 1350 1343 1999 Median SAT Score 1300 1250 1200 1178 1159 1150 1155 1128 1100 1050 1000 1050 1010 1010 950 900 These nine measures provide the basis for categorizing The Top American Research Universities. We believe that it is useful to identify those institutions that compete at the top levels (within the top 25) and at the next level (within the top 26–50) on one or more of these measures. Although we continue the practice of showing private and public institutional categories separately, we focus primarily on the categorization that includes all research universities within a national context. In some ways, we find this to be more useful, since the competition for faculty, students, and revenue often puts private and public universities into direct competition with each other on a national basis. The Impact of Enrollment and Medical Schools on Research Competitiveness Some universities have remarkable success in the competition described by these data, but the critical determinants of university performance do not appear so clearly. In conversations among university people, two elements receive much attention. Some argue that increasing undergraduate enrollments brings a major competitive advantage. Others believe that the presence of a medical school gives universities a competitive advantage in today’s research marketplace. While our data indicate that enrollment and medical schools may very well make some difference, the impact is not as straightforward or as significant as one might assume. Private and Public University Enrollment, Federal Research, and Faculty Numbers: Most observers of American research universities recognize that private universities tend to have smaller enrollments than their public counterparts. As indicated above in our discussion of the quality engine model, enrollment size responds to many pressures but probably reflects the financial model underlying the institution. Because research universities are complex organizations, however, simple assumptions about the relationship of enrollment to institutional competitiveness in research and student quality generally do not hold. To explore the impact of enrollment, we first examined the relationship between undergraduate headcount enrollment and federal research. We made a few adjustments to the data. For the analysis, we excluded stand-alone medical institutions. These institutions are significant competitors in the research marketplace but do not include undergraduate education within their primary mission. After these adjustments, the universe that we examined included those 575 universities reporting any federal research between 1990 and 1999, although we focused primarily on institutions with over $20 million in federal research. The scatterplot displays undergraduate enrollment and federal research for the 129 major research universities in this adjusted universe with over $20 million in federal expenditures. It clearly Large and small illustrates that private universities generally have institutions, private smaller enrollments than do their public counterparts, and public, appear but at the same time, it at all levels of research shows no simple linear relationship between performance. undergraduate enrollment size and success in the federal research competition. Large and small institutions, private and public, appear at all levels of research performance. The same pattern also holds for those research universities with less than $20 million. At every level of federal research, public universities tend to T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 25 Undergraduate Enrollment and Federal Research: Over $20 Million Universities 40,000 Private (N=43) Public (N=86) 1999 Undergraduate Enrollment 35,000 30,000 25,000 20,000 Public median: 17,857 15,000 10,000 5,000 0 $0 Private median: 6,108 $50,000 $100,000 $150,000 $200,000 $250,000 $300,000 $350,000 $800,000 1999 Federal Research (x $1,000) be larger than are their private counterparts, but the relationship between undergraduate size and federal research success is weak. Enrollment size is of some significance, nonetheless, in understanding the different financial models that underlie private and public research university competition. In our model of research universities described above, what matters is the availability of funds to invest in the acquisition and support of research faculty and of quality undergraduate programs. In the case of public universities, the size of an institution’s undergraduate enrollment responds to many pressures. In some instances, public universities grow in response to state mandates for increased public access to undergraduate education. Such institutions may well have many students and may use the revenue from enrollment to support a large portfolio of instructional and service enterprises that are of significant value but are unrelated to research or to the acquisition of quality students. In the event that teaching and Page 26 service do not produce revenue exceeding their costs, their contribution to research or student competitiveness will not be great. Large institutions may also incur a quality penalty. In accommodating the large number of undergraduates required by state access goals, they may not have the resources to invest in the programs and other amenities that attract the highest quality undergraduates. Nonetheless, because most public universities receive substantial portions of their total budgets based on undergraduate enrollments, it is not surprising to discover that they generally grow larger than their private counterparts, whose revenue is not as enrollment driven. Indeed, private universities have between one-fourth to less than one-half of the median undergraduate enrollment of public institutions at every level of federal research. However, undergraduate enrollment has an obvious impact on the number of faculty members at an institution. In public universities, the larger number of students can support a larger number Enrollment and Medical Schools of faculty than at their smaller private counterparts. Nonetheless, if the larger public institution hires mostly teaching faculty — individuals who do not perform significant amounts of competitive research — then the increased faculty size will enhance research competitiveness less than the increase in faculty numbers might suggest. While public institutions support larger undergraduate student bodies and have larger complements of personnel than their private counterparts, this added size does not necessarily enhance their ability to capture large research portfolios or to enhance the quality of their students. Although the best public research competitors have substantial undergraduate enrollments (the five top public university performers in federal research have enrollments in the 15,000 to 30,000 range), the four private universities in the same range all have less than 12,000 in undergraduate enrollment. Again, we believe that this speaks to the underlying financial models. Public university enrollments may help to generate the revenue that allows them to compete for research faculty, but private universities may not gain much benefit from larger undergraduate enrollments. Unlike public universities, whose undergraduate enrollments respond to public policies and funding priorities, private universities may set their enrollments to meet programmatic needs. Private universities need enough students to populate the academic programs that they offer. An institution with a small number of academic specialties may require a smaller undergraduate student body than an institution with many specialties. Elite private universities often subsidize the tuition of their students from internal funds (using endowment earnings as well as various forms of federal and state financial aid) in order to compete successfully for the best students. Consequently, for private universities, increasing the size of the undergraduate student body may not produce a financial benefit but may instead increase their costs. For these reasons, it is likely that private institutions have a self-limiting enrollment structure scaled to match the academic complexity of the institution as well as its investment in competing for high- quality students. As a result, the benefit that a larger enrollment brings to the private university’s research competitiveness is relatively limited. This may help to explain the narrower range of enrollment sizes for private universities compared to the wider range observed in comparable public institutions. An additional perspective on the issue of enrollment size involves the relationships between graduate student enrollment and federal research. Some graduate student enrollment, especially of those in the pursuit of Ph.D.s, reflects the size and capacity of research programs, but other graduate students are in various forms of terminal master’s degree programs that have much less of a relationship to the university’s research agenda. Universities with larger undergraduate enrollment gain an opportunity to support a larger number of graduate students For public universities, as teaching assistants. The plot of graduate student increasing undergraduate headcount and federal enrollment may help to research for the major research universities with generate the revenue that over $20 million in federal research is instructive. allows them to compete Among both private and for research faculty. For public institutions, approximately the same relationship privates, more students exists between the number of graduate students and may not provide a the size of the institution’s federal research expenditures. financial benefit but The difference in the instead increase costs median size of the graduate student populations of due to tuition subsidies. private and public universities is somewhat less than the difference observed for undergraduate student enrollment but it is still substantial. The scatterplot of undergraduate and graduate enrollment illustrates that while both private and public universities demonstrate a relationship between undergraduate and graduate enrollment, the relationship is substantially higher for public universities, as we would expect given the role of graduate students in the teaching mission of large public institutions. T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 27 Graduate Enrollment and Federal Research: Over $20 Million Universities 16,000 14,000 Private (N=43) Public (N=86) 1999 Graduate Enrollment 12,000 Public R2=0.32 10,000 Private R2=0.33 8,000 6,000 Public median: 5,600 4,000 Private median: 3,280 2,000 0 $0 $50,000 $100,000 $150,000 $200,000 $250,000 $300,000 $350,000 $800,000 1999 Federal Research (x $1,000) Undergraduate vs. Graduate Enrollment: Over $20 Million Universities 40,000 1999 Undergraduate Enrollment 35,000 Private (N=43) Public R2=0.57 Public (N=86) 30,000 25,000 20,000 Private R2=0.37 15,000 10,000 5,000 0 0 2,000 4,000 6,000 8,000 10,000 12,000 14,000 16,000 1999 Graduate Enrollment Page 28 Enrollment and Medical Schools While enrollment, both undergraduate and graduate, helps us to understand some of the competitive elements in the construction of a successful research university, we do not have a measure for the most important element: the number of active research faculty. Unfortunately, no methodology currently exists to capture this number accurately. While all universities report various faculty counts to national agencies and in response to a variety of surveys, the methodologies used to produce these numbers vary significantly by institution, as described in a paper published on TheCenter website. The result is that comparisons based on faculty counts are unreliable, mostly because the data from the institutions are not comparable. Further complicating the use of faculty counts is the wide range of faculty functions in universities of different types. Some institutions have many individuals classified as faculty in instructional and service activities, while other institutions have most of their faculty in research functions. If we could identify the full-time equivalent research faculty on a standard basis across institutions, our hypothesis predicts that this number would be an excellent predictor of institutional research success, as it often is in comparing the research success of individual guilds. Reliable data on research faculty would also permit an analysis of comparative faculty productivity by institution, a task not possible with currently available faculty data. Medical Schools and Federal Research: Medical schools offer another point of comparison between institutions. A common perception holds that institutions with medical schools have an advantage in a research competition where significant sums go to biomedical and life science projects. Indeed, only eight institutions out of the top 50 in federal research succeed at this level without a medical school. The importance of life science research for many high-performing universities (which is visible in the data table of Institutional Characteristics for Institutions with Over $20 million in Federal Research) reinforces the belief in the importance of a medical school in the competition for federal research dollars. Although medical schools frequently have highquality research faculty who compete successfully for federal grants and contracts, the data do not demonstrate that the existence of a medical school alone guarantees a nationally competitive research university faculty. Universities with and without medical schools appear at all levels of research competition. Although only one institution without a medical school competes among the top ten institutions in federal research, many institutions without medical schools compete successfully in each Comparisons based subsequent group of ten among the top 130 instituon faculty counts are tions (excluding stand-alone medical schools) ranked by unreliable, mostly federal research. because the data from The primary functions of medical schools, the institutions are not which include preparing future physicians and comparable. participating in the clinical enterprise, do not necessarily require high levels of federally funded basic research. Universities without medical schools often have significant investments in biomedical research in departments of biology, microbiology, bioengineering, and similar disciplines, and they often compete effectively against the medical school research faculty at other institutions. The key contribution that a medical school makes to a research university is the generation of surplus revenue that can subsidize the development of high-quality biomedical and life science research. Most, but not all, medical schools prove capable of generating such surpluses and have the commitment to invest such funds into research. Nonetheless, universities with and without medical schools perform at comparable levels of research competitiveness. The chart included here shows the top 130 research universities divided into groups of ten based upon federal research, with each cluster divided by those institutions with medical schools and those without. In this chart, we removed the institutions that are stand-alone medical schools, T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 29 as our discussion here focuses on comprehensive research universities that include medical schools. Universities with and without medical schools appear in all clusters of federal research within the top 130 universities represented by this chart. Of the 80 universities with medical schools, 14 institutions do not have sufficient federal research activity to rank among the top 130 institutions included in this chart. Universities with and without Medical Schools by 1999 Federal Research Rank Medical No Medical 10 9 Number of Institutions 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 111–120 101–110 81–90 91–100 71–80 61–70 51–60 41–50 31–40 21–30 11–20 1–10 0 121–130 1 Universities Grouped by National Rank When a medical school generates a surplus and invests that in support of research, its presence as part of the university will make a major contribution to its research competitiveness. The existence of a medical school with the capacity to support research, then, contributes to the university’s research competitiveness. A medical school alone does not guarantee competitiveness. ance of a university in terms of its federal research comes from the success of its faculty in competing for these funds. While this is obvious, it bears emphasis that this competition is fierce. Success rates for proposals submitted to the NSF and NIH vary, but in recent years, over all projects, about 30% of the proposals submitted received funding. The resulting expenditures by universities from federal funds reflect the aggregate success of the institution in acquiring and supporting research faculty who compete successfully for these funds. Universities increase or decrease in their research performance based primarily on this competition. Change in Rank Order: Many observers focus on the ranking of research universities, including the authors of this report. However, overemphasis on rank order as the primary reflection of competitiveness can obscure some important distinctions. Ranking, by virtue of its evenly spaced series from number one on down, gives the impression that ranking also reflects an even distribution of performance. That is certainly not the case here. In fact, the performance gap between universities at the top of the ranking scale is much greater than the difference separating universities farther down the scale. As the following figure illustrates, the distance that separates universities (median, low, and high) within groups of ten decreases rapidly as rank declines. Gap between Adjacent Ranked Universities by 1999 Federal Research Rank $30,000 Change in Competitive Performance on Federal Research Competition in university research implies gains and losses. University faculty offer more quality research proposals than the various federal agencies can support. Primarily through the process of peer review, although sometimes through the direct appropriation of federal dollars to individual research projects or institutions without peer review (this process is called earmarking), some faculty projects receive funding while others do not. The perform- Page 30 Gap between Institutions (x $1,000) Highest Gap $25,000 Median Gap * Lowest Gap $20,000 $15,000 $14,165 $10,000 $5,194 $5,000 $3,970 $0 $781 1–10 11–20 21–30 31–40 $1,145 41–50 $628 51–100 Universities Grouped by National Rank * The gap between Johns Hopkins and the second-ranked institution ($402 million) is atypical and therefore excluded from this analysis. Change in Federal Research For example, the median gap between each of the universities ranked 1–10 is about $14.2 million, while the median gap for ranks 11–20 is less than two-thirds of that at $5.2 million. Thus, to improve in rank, holding all other elements constant, a university in the top ten might need to increase its federal expenditures by roughly 6% while a university in the 11–20 range would only need to increase by about 2%. In practice, not all elements are constant, since a change in the rank of any particular university is a function of its position relative not to the median of its group but to the performance of institutions immediately above and below. The variation in the gap between institutions of similar research performance is large, and the amount of change required to move up one rank varies substantially by institution. Improvement or decline in rank also depends on the behavior of other universities. If the institution one position higher declines in performance, the university below may improve its rank without having improved its performance at all. A university that improves its performance may nonetheless decline in rank because the institution below it made a greater improvement and the institution above it improved by the same amount. The figures included here clarify these relationships. We looked at all universities with $20 million or more in federal research over a period of ten years (1990–1999). We divided them into two groups: those whose federal research increased in constant 1998 dollars, and those whose federal research declined. We then tracked the change in rank for each group and arranged them by the size of their 1999 federal research expenditures. Of those who gained in expenditures, some also improved their rank, but many did not. The amount of rank change over the ten-year period increases as the amount of federal research decreases, illustrating the impact of the smaller gap between universities at lower ranks. The second chart shows the rank change for institutions that experienced a decline in federal research during the ten-year period. All of those in the higher ranks declined significantly in research volume and declined somewhat in rank with the exception of Johns Hopkins. Although Hopkins lost $29.8 million in constant dollars over the ten years, it easily maintained its top position in the ranking. The ranking of universities helps to illustrate the general characteristics of research competitiveness, but change in rank is less helpful as an indicator of individual university performance over time. A better indicator is the actual change in federal research expenditures, expressed in constant 1998 dollars, which gives a useful comparative context for assessing institutional performance. An absolute decline in constant-dollar federal research expenditures is a relatively clear event for this decade, since there was an increase in the total federal dollars available. An absolute increase, Over $20 Million Universities with a Decrease in Federal Research: Change in National Rank, 1990–99 Over $20 Million Universities with an Increase in Federal Research: Change in National Rank, 1990–99 $800,000 $350,000 $350,000 Declined in Rank $300,000 1999 Federal Research (x $1,000) 1999 Federal Research (x $1,000) $400,000 Improved in Rank $250,000 $200,000 $150,000 $100,000 Declined in Rank Improved in Rank $300,000 $250,000 $200,000 $150,000 $100,000 $50,000 $50,000 $0 -25 0 25 50 75 100 Net Change in National Rank T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s $0 -50 -25 0 Net Change in National Rank Page 31 Growth in Federal Research, 1990–99 (in Constant 1998 Dollars) Federal Research in Constant 1998 Dollars (in billions) 16 Total Federal Research grew by 25.3% between 1990 and 1999. 14 12 Over $20 Million Public Universities had an overall growth rate of 27.1%. 10 8 6 Over $20 Million Private Universities had an overall growth rate of 18.3%. 4 2 All universities with less than $20 million grew by 49.8%. 0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 however, offers two possible interpretations. In the first case, an institution might increase its research expenditures, but at a rate less than the rate of increase for all research university federal expenditures. In this decade, the overall increase was 25.3%. In a relative sense, this may reflect a decline in an institution’s share of federal research, as it has not grown at the same rate as the pool of funds. In the second case, an institution might increase its constant-dollar research expenditures at a rate in Change in Federal Research, 1990–99: Over $20 Million Universities (in Constant 1998 Dollars) Increase Greater than 25.3% (N=82) Increase Less than 25.3% (N=46) Decrease in Research (N=26) Number of Universities with Increase 24 16 8 Number of Universities with Decrease 58 30 18 Private Public (N=48) (N=106) Page 32 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 excess of the increase of the pool, thus also increasing its share. The table below displays those universities with over $20 million that experienced each of these three cases over the past ten years. Private and Public University Shares of Federal Research: The shifts in market share offer some additional insight. The past decade has seen the emergence of a number of public universities competing successfully for federal research dollars. As a result, the distribution of market share in federal research expenditures has shifted over the period of 1990–1999. Private universities with over $20 million in federal research lost 2.2% market share during the decade. This was the only category of universities amount our four research groups that lost market share. Because the total amount of federal dollars grew during those ten years, the private institutions in this category gained $896 million, but because the total federal expenditures grew at a faster rate, they actually lost market share. Public research universities with over $1 million gained 1.97%, with most of the gain occurring in Change in Federal Research Change in Federal Research Market Share, 1990–99: By Research Group and Control (in Constant 1998 Dollars) Over $20M $5–$20M $1–$5M Under $1M (N=154) (N=97) (N=128) (N=238) 1.0% 0.84% 0.74% 0.5% 0.39% 0.13% 0.08% 0.02% 0.00% -0.5% Private Public -1.0% -1.5% -2.0% -2.20% -2.5% the $20 million and $5–$20 million categories. Private universities with less than $20 million gained 0.23% market share in the decade. A final reflection on the private-public distribution of federal research compares private and public university research expenditures. The graph includes two lines plotted on the same scale: one for the top 100 private universities and the other for top 100 public universities, both arranged in order of their Top 100 Private vs. Top 100 Public Institutions: 1999 Federal Research $800,000 $350,000 1999 Federal Research (x $1,000) Percentage Change 0.0% federal research expenditures. The purpose of this graph is to show the relative competitiveness of private and public research universities in acquiring federal research support. For the first 12 private and the first 12 public universities, the private universities have a higher level of federal research. After than, this pattern reverses, and from rank 13 on down, public universities have greater federal research expenditures than private universities. This pattern indicates that the top private universities continue to succeed in maintaining their preeminence as competitive research performers. However, the number of private universities that can compete with their public counterparts falls off after rank 12. Although we have not yet analyzed this pattern in detail, we expect that tax-based funding provides the revenue supporting many public universities’ investments in research-competitive faculty and facilities. Private universities often find it more difficult to generate the revenue required to compete for faculty and to provide the necessary research support. As a result, while many private universities remain competitive, they find themselves at a Private Public $300,000 $250,000 Rank 12 $200,000 $150,000 $100,000 $50,000 $20 Million $0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Control Rank T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 33 disadvantage compared to their public competitors on one side and their better-endowed private competitors on the other. Patterns of Improvement and Decline in Federal Research Expenditures: Although we can summarize the aggregate behavior of research university competitiveness over time, as measured by federal research expenditures, the patterns of change for individual universities pose a different challenge. Some institutions demonstrate predictable patterns, with a steady increase or decrease in their expenditures. For others, the data change substantially over the ten-year period, rising many millions in one year and falling an equal or greater amount in subsequent years. These larger changes reflect many circumstances that are particular to each university. Institutions can receive grants that include capital expenditures. As the university spends these one-time dollars, the reported federal expenditures for that year will spike upward, only to fall back to a normal level in subsequent years. Institutions can gain or lose large grants, producing major fluctuations in their expenditure patterns. Sometimes, universities improve their methods of data reporting to the federal government, producing a one-time increase in the reported revenue. Whatever the case, an explanation for the particular history of any university’s research competitiveness requires a specific and detailed understanding of that institution’s research activities in comparison to similarly competitive counterparts. The explanations for a rise or fall in reported results will vary significantly from institution to institution. An illustration of the complexity of a university’s research performance as reflected by federal expenditures is visible in the graphs of ten universities displayed in the two figures below. The first figure graphs the ten-year performance of five universities (1 private, 4 public) that showed the greatest percentage improvement in their research performance (excluding stand-alone medical institutions). The second figure graphs a comparable group of five universities (3 private, 2 public) that declined the most in research performance during the same ten- Research Universities with the Largest Percentage Increase in Federal Research: 1990–1999 Federal Research in Constant 1998 Dollars (x $1,000) $100,000 $80,000 $60,000 $40,000 $20,000 $0 1990 1991 Page 34 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 Change in Federal Research year period. The institutions all fall within a group reporting expenditures in the $20–$90 million range in 1999. The graphs display expenditures in constant 1998 dollars. Some of these institutions report a steady rise or fall in expenditures; others show major changes from one year to the next. To understand the competitive circumstances of the federal research marketplace that these data reflect, each institution would need to review its ten-year data and compare this performance history with its near competitors. For all of the similarity in their organizational models, American research universities have many different strategies for success. No single pattern explains the success or difficulty encountered by universities in competing for federal research and outstanding students. Our understanding of research university behavior indicates that the most important element is the creation of revenue to subsidize the acquisition of high-quality scarce faculty and student talent and support for the research enterprise. At the same time, each university has an internal strategy for the effective investment of its revenue. Many characteristics determine a university’s ability to compete for the scarce elements that make a research institution. No single characteristic appears to explain competitive achievement, but instead, the right combination of elements matched with an institution’s resources and opportunities is what appears to drive the most successful institutions. To maintain or improve their competitiveness in these marketplaces, universities almost certainly need to understand the relationship between their investments in research and student support and the results that they achieve. Some universities may be wealthy enough to avoid the discipline of measuring results, but most institutions are not. Our goal in this publication is to provide useful data that present institutions within their competitive context as a tool for measuring and improving research university performance. Research Universities with the Largest Percentage Decrease in Federal Research: 1990–1999 Federal Research in Constant 1998 Dollars (x $1,000) $100,000 $80,000 $60,000 $40,000 $20,000 $0 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s 1996 1997 1998 Page 35 1999 Page 36 Data Tables Part I The Top American Research Universities TheCenter determines the Top American Research Universities by their rank on nine different measures: Total Research, Federal Research, Endowment Assets, Annual Giving, National Academy Members, Faculty Awards, Doctorates Granted, Postdoctoral Appointees, and Median SAT Scores. (The Source Notes section of this study provides detailed information on each of the nine indicators.) The tables group research institutions according to how many times they rank in the top 25 on each of these nine measures. The top category includes those universities that rank in the top 25 on all nine indicators. The bottom category includes universities with only one of the nine measures ranked in the top 25. Within these groups, institutions are then sorted by how many times they rank between 26 and 50 on the nine performance variables, with ties listed alphabetically. A similar methodology produces a second set of institutions — those ranked 26 through 50 on the same nine measures. For the purpose of this study, TheCenter includes only those institutions that had at least $20 million in federal research expenditures in FY 1999. This is the same dollar cutoff used in our last report. The first two tables list each institution with the most current data available for each measure and its corresponding national rank (i.e., rank among all institutions regardless of whether they are privately or publicly controlled). The third and fourth tables provide the same nine data measures but with the groupings determined by the control rank (i.e., rank among all private or all public institutions). Institutions ranking in the top 25 on at least one measure are included in the tables with the (1–25) identifier, while those ranking 26 through 50 are found in the tables labeled with the (26–50) header. • The Top American Research Universities (1–25) identifies the 50 institutions (26 private, 24 public) that rank in the top 25 nationally on at least one of the nine measures. • The Top American Research Universities (26–50) identifies the 37 institutions (9 private, 28 public) that rank 26 through 50 nationally on at least one of the nine measures. • The Top Private Research Universities (1–25) identifies the 36 private institutions that rank in the top 25 among all private universities on at least one of the nine measures. • The Top Public Research Universities (1–25) identifies the 46 public institutions that rank in the top 25 among all public universities on at least one of the nine measures. • The Top Private and Public Research Universities (26–50) identifies the 12 private and 31 public institutions that rank 26 through 50 among their private or public counterparts on at least one of the nine measures. Many research universities rank highly both nationally and among their public or private peers and therefore appear in more than one table. For example, of the 36 private institutions in the Top Private Research Universities (1–25) table, 27 universities also appear in the Top American Research Universities (1–25) table. Data found in these tables may not always match the figures published by the original source. TheCenter makes adjustments, when necessary, to ensure that the data reflect the activity at a single campus rather than that of a multiple campus institution or state university system. When data are missing from the original source, TheCenter may substitute another figure if available. A full discussion of this subject, and the various adjustments or substitutions made to the original data, is in the Data Notes section of this report. TheCenter presents these tables, along with last year’s top universities, in Microsoft Excel spreadsheets on its website [http://thecenter.ufl.edu]. T h e To p A m e r i c a n R e s e a r c h U n i v e r s i t i e s Page 37 TheCenter University Organization, Governance, and Competitiveness John V. Lombardi Diane D. Craig Elizabeth D. Capaldi Denise S. Gater The Top American Research Universities August 2002 An Annual Report from The Lombardi Program on Measuring University Performance Contents University Governance and Organization ....................................................................................................3 Definitions........................................................................................................................................3 Quality Engines ................................................................................................................................5 University Administrative Shell ........................................................................................................5 Governance Prototypes ....................................................................................................................6 Political Context ..............................................................................................................................9 Purpose and Functions of Governance ............................................................................................12 Imperative of Statewide Governance ..............................................................................................15 Relationship of Governance to Research University Competitiveness ......................................................16 Cost, Complexity, Regulation, and Money ....................................................................................18 Endowment-Equivalent ..................................................................................................................20 Some References on University Organization and Finance ......................................................................25 Appendix: Endowment-Equivalent Data and Calculations ......................................................................29 Acknowledgments The authors gratefully acknowledge the support of Mr. Lewis M. Schott, whose generous contribution established the Lombardi Program on Measuring University Perfomance. The Top American Research Universities Page 1 University Governance and Organization Research universities live in complex contexts, compete in many different marketplaces, and perform a bewildering array of highly sophisticated services for many diverse constituencies. Although research universities focus their efforts primarily on the key dimensions of teaching and research, they engage in a wide range of additional activities derived from the expertise and resources accumulated in support of teaching and research. With the dramatic expansion of higher education, and particularly public higher education, in the post World War II years and then again in the 1960s, institutions became much more complex and the organization of their governance became an evermore popular topic, especially among political leadership in the various states. Public university governance and organization, a topic for scholarly interest since the pre-war years of the 1930s, became a major concern in most states throughout the last half of the twentieth century and continues to preoccupy institutions, their governance boards, and their political supporters into the early years of this century. Definitions In the discussion of university governance and organization, as is often the case with other universityrelated topics, we immediately encounter a series of ambiguous terms. American universities have a remarkably imprecise vocabulary to describe their activities. Take the word “university.” While everyone agrees this refers to an institution of post-secondary education, the range of such institutions that use this term is large. Small private and public institutions with modest to almost invisible graduate programs and a narrow range of disciplines as well as major research universities with extensive graduate and professional programs and an extended array of disciplines all carry the same name: University. Further complicating the nomenclature, we have the terms “school” and “college.” Sometimes context makes the definition clear: “The engineering college prospered.” In other situations, context is ambiguous: “My daughter visited five colleges before deciding on Stanford.” We do not know from this statement whether the daughter visited Oberlin, Pomona, Smith, Amherst, and Stanford or visited Michigan, Berkeley, Minnesota, Illinois, and Stanford before choosing Stanford. “College,” like “university,” refers not only to institutions large and small – all of which offer undergraduate degrees from the AA to the BA or BS but also The Top American Research Universities to subdivisions of the university like journalism or business. “School” is equally ambiguous. While almost no one, in formal contexts, refers to a college or university as a “school,” students frequently use the word “school” to refer to their university. “What do you think of the school so far?” the junior will ask the freshman at a university event. “We have great school spirit among the students,” says another. In this context, clearly “school” is equivalent to the institution – whether university or college – even though in organizational terms universities use the name “college” or “school” for academic subdivisions. The academic meaning of these terms also varies from institution to institution. Some have only schools (medicine, engineering, music) such as Johns Hopkins. Some have only colleges of medicine, engineering, or fine arts. In some institutions, the school distinction is reserved for the non-arts and sciences American universities units, and arts and sciences units carry the title of college (Indiana have a remarkably University Bloomington). Finally, in some institutions a imprecise vocabulary to college is a larger academic administrative unit under which describe their activities. schools may exist (a college of fine arts with its school of music and school of art). Equal variety attends the designation of campus officers above the level of dean. Presidents, chancellors, provosts, executive vice presidents, deputy chancellors, and other titles serve purposes of significance to local participants in the institutional culture. In some institutional settings the president presides over the system and chancellors preside over the individual institutions; in others the chancellor serves the system as chief executive and the presidents serve the universities. Most private universities have presidents as chief executive officers, but some have chancellors. Second-order administrators take the title from their superiors; so vice presidents serve presidents, and vice chancellors serve chancellors. When institutions and their systems become complex, universities identify intermediaries in their hierarchies and titles such as provost or deputy chancellor or executive vice president appear with responsibilities greater than a vice president or vice chancellor but less than a president or chancellor. Page 2 The title of provost confuses those outside the academic environment, and most provosts carry the additional title of vice president for academic affairs. If the message that the title “provost” makes a vice president first among vice presidents is insufficient, some acquire the additional honorific of senior vice president for academic affairs to add weight to the title of provost. In some places, where the administrative functions of finance and business operations hold great institutional significance, such an officer may also be a senior vice president, although whether that trumps a provost or executive vice president is mostly a function of institutional tradition. A “campus” is an important concept in most universities. The campus defines geography, a location that in some original sense represented the institution. When colleges and universities were small and selfcontained, the notion of college and campus coincided. With the advent of large single institutions, remote branch locations, and multiple-institution university systems, the precision of the concept of campus coinciding with university blurred. Many large universities have separate campuses in the same city, sometimes physically connected sometimes not. University at Buffalo, for example, has two campuses separated by three miles. Even when the physical space of the university is contiguous, such as the University of Michigan at Ann Arbor, people speak of the medical campus, the north campus, the south campus, and the central campus. The archetypical small college remains, however, embedded in our imaginations. Many observers still use the term “campus” to refer to a university that may have two or more distinguishable physical locations where it delivers its programs. If the definitions used for single institutions are difficult, imagine the naming challenge for systems, groupings of institutions in the complex governance organizations discussed here. Although, for various political and administrative reasons, systems of institutions choose different naming conventions, we treat all of them as systems. Sometimes, as is the case of the University of California and other similarly constituted systems, the rhetorical language implies one university existing in many different locations. This concept has some validity related to the formal authority of the system, but in practice individual campus-based institutions within the system function in ways that mimic single campus research universities. The key participants for research universities – faculty and students – live and work primarily in one place and their academic lives and accomplishments revolve around mostly place-bound resources and activities. Page 3 In research university contexts, the campus location also identifies the universe of individuals who participate in decisions about the quality of research and the content of the teaching program. Recruitment of faculty and students and promotion and tenure decisions about faculty usually reflect primarily place-specific criteria, even when the system is styled as a single university with multiple campuses. Students and faculty make choices related to campus location, not system designation. In California or Massachusetts, a student or faculty member affiliates with Berkeley or UMass Amherst, not with the University of California or the University of Massachusetts writ large, even though systems have their own characteristics that may enhance or detract from the desirability of campuses. Some university systems seek to present themselves as a single university with multiple locations as a way to show the system’s assets as a single large resource rather than as the disaggregated and less impressive subtotals of the individual campuses. Some systems also promote the notion of a single university for statewide political purposes or in marketing their programs internationally. Another distinction involves the branch campus. While university systems may coordinate or govern multiple university campuses with relatively autonomous academic decision-making authority, many individual institutions (standing alone or within systems) also have branch campuses. Branch campuses generally depend heavily on the parent campus for academic direction, usually do not have autonomous academic personnel decision-making authority for promotion and tenure, and often provide only a subset of the full curriculum offered by the parent. In our work here and for the purposes of understanding research universities, we use the term “university” to apply to a single campus-based institution that has substantially independent academic decision-making authority and admits students primarily with reference to local standards. These campuses hire, promote, and tenure faculty through processes that substantially rely on locally referenced campus standards and usually have tenure defined by specific campus location. We use the term “system” to apply to governance organizations of many types that collect these university campuses into organizational and managerial constructs of greater or lesser complexity and integration. Systems rarely combine campus-based research institutions into a single functioning university entity although a few systems share some academic units across several institutions. Definitions For our purposes, we use the terms “institution” and “university” interchangeably to refer to the campusbased research universities that have been the focus of these annual reports on The Top American Research Universities, and we refer to the larger organizations that in the public sector govern groups of universities (however named or organized as described below) as “systems.” For example, the University of California is formally one university with multiple campuses. But for the purposes of our discussion, we see the University of California as a system that governs multiple campusbased research universities such as UCLA or Berkeley. The goal of these reports, of course, is to understand the competitive success of individual research universities, and in this report we look at the complex organizational models within which they operate. Quality Engines As we discussed in our previous publication (The Top American Research Universities, 2001), research In the academic core, the faculty guilds control teaching and research quality the work of the faculty. A third sustains the research of the faculty and their many collaborators, while a fourth translates those research accomplishments into patents, licenses, and other assets of value to the nation and the world. The core of this engine, which we described more fully in last year’s report, is composed of departments or programs that resemble guilds – defined as organized collections of individual experts joined by their shared commitment to a particular methodological and subject approach to knowledge and driven by a national and international system of common standards and criteria for quality. These guilds – whether familiar ones like history, English, chemistry, psychology, philosophy, physics, and mathematics or newer ones like neuroscience or biomedical engineering – control faculty identification, selection, promotion, and tenure. Through this process, the guilds function as self-perpetuating communities whose quality depends on the rigor of the standards they apply to those who would become permanent members. The guilds and their work are at the nucleus of a broader university environment… an environment that is enriched with student services, general support and enterprises complementary to research and teaching universities function as quality engines. They accumulate resources of all kinds to support the highest possible levels of faculty and student quality. Faculty and students, pursuing their individual goals within the context of the university’s academic programs and guilds, develop their skills and use them to create additional value either in the form of enhanced capabilities as graduates (at all levels from undergraduate through professional school to the PhD) or of contributions to new knowledge through research. In achieving these aims, the quality engine of the American research university operates multiple separate domains, nonetheless connected within the boundaries of the campus-based institution itself. One domain drives the teaching enterprise at the undergraduate level; another connects graduate and professional studies to The Top American Research Universities University Administrative Shell Although the guilds hold the keys to the effectiveness of the American research university’s quality engine, they rarely exist independently of the support and management provided by the university shell. The shell, also described more fully in last year’s report, serves as the organizational construct that acquires money and other resources needed by the guilds. It provides the administrative infrastructure that supports the guilds and their work, creates the connective mechanisms that link the guilds for the purposes of undergraduate education and other joint enterprises, and protects the guilds and their members from external pressures that might impair their effectiveness. The public sees the shell as the administration of the university with its boards and administrative offi- Page 4 An active administrative “shell” positions the institution as a whole, builds resources and helps to attract faculty, students and benefactors cers and its hierarchically represented organizational structure. The guilds know that this hierarchy belongs primarily to the shell and does not define the authority structure of quality engine’s academic core. While shell agents can manage money and resources, they do not directly control the content or quality of the institution’s academic work, which belongs to and is primarily supervised and managed by the faculty. The faculty, in turn, define academic standards in cooperation and collaboration with colleagues in similar guilds throughout the nation. Nonetheless, the work within the shell is essential to the success of the quality engine’s guilds. Everything the guilds seek in the pursuit of quality requires support: faculty, students, libraries, laboratories, computers, buildings, travel, research assistance, and the like. All of these elements need money. The defining function of the shell is to acquire the maximum resources possible in support of the guilds’ missions of teaching and research. Teaching and research do not directly command a sufficient share of resources in the open marketplace to pay the full cost of their production, and shell agents work endlessly to identify additional sources of funding. This involves development or fund-raising), political lobbying for additional state and federal support, encouragement of grant and contract application and awards to expand the research base, development of commercial or quasi-commercial businesses derived from the university’s intellectual property, and the efficient and effective operation of the institution and its various affiliated enterprises. Our interest, we must emphasize, focuses on only one segment of the American higher education mar- Page 5 ketplace: major research universities defined as institutions with at least $20 million of federally funded research expenditures per year. This group of about 160 institutions controls over 90% of all the federally funded research expenditures reported by the 600 institutions that share this support. They compete fiercely for the funds that make this research possible; for the services of the most productive, creative, and innovative research faculty; and for the resources to recruit the best undergraduate, graduate, and professional students into their midst. This competition drives the behavior of America’s research universities, and our work over the past few years has attempted to understand this competition. We have described the characteristics, and we present various indicators of institutional success in the competition. We have explored the impact of size and medical schools on the competition, for example, and we have looked closely at the mechanisms by which these quality engines support and improve quality. As we continue to explore this competitive behavior, the wide range of organizational and governance structures within which American research universities function intrigues us. We examined the extensive literature on the organization and governance of public and private universities and reviewed the many forms of governance to discover how the organizational structures of institutional governance influence research university competition. Governance Prototypes The variety of organizational structures that govern American research universities ranges from a simple model that places a university campus in a single, notfor-profit corporation responsible to a self-perpetuating Governance Prototypes board of trustees to the ornate configurations of state university systems with their overlapping boards of regents and trustees, their higher education coordinating commissions, and their multiple subsidiary foundations and other enterprises. Despite this range of governance, research university quality engines – with their immediate shell and core academic guilds – compete with each other in almost identical ways. Governance structures take on forms that adapt to the challenges of external environments rather than respond primarily to the needs of the academic guilds they govern. Among private institutions, governance models change little over the period of a century or more. For many public institutions, however, governance mechanisms that link the institution to the state that sponsors and owns them often change – sometimes dramatically. In our review of organizational models, we identified a number of prototypes, drawing on the extensive literature on this topic, which we review briefly below. These models represent a simplification of the detailed formal, organizational structure of institutions and systems as reflected in their documents, and our own involvement with a number of institutions clearly indicates that behavior and the balance of authority and responsibility can vary considerably from what the documents imply. Our prototypes represent a stylized version of the 19 different structures identified by the Education Commission of the States, in part because we look at organization from the perspective of the research university rather than from the perspective of the state or corporation that governs the institutions. Universities generally fall into three main groups containing a number of sub-categories: • The first group includes those universities that have a single governing board for a campusbased research institution with direct authority and responsibility for the operation and management of the institution. Some institutions in this group, primarily private, have self-perpetuating governing boards with complete authority and responsibility for all aspects of the university’s operation. Others, primarily public, have mostly politically appointed governing boards with an obligation to report to legislatures, governors, or statewide boards or commissions that may limit the institutional board’s authority and responsibility in various ways. • The second group includes multiple campusbased public institutions governed by a common statewide board. In this group, the campus-based institutions may report to the statewide board directly or through a system executive. • The third group of public institutions has a local governing board for the campus institution, and this local board has a subset of powers derived from or delegated by a statewide board. The dis- A competitive university must continually fuel its quality engine with people, capacity and resources The Top American Research Universities Page 6 tribution of authority and responsibility between the statewide board and the local board, and between state-level executives and campus-level executives, varies widely. These relationships tend to change with some frequency in response to challenges, opportunities, personal ambitions of individual actors, and legislative and executive branch preferences. When a university has a single board for a single campus, the relationships of authority and responsibility appear much more clearly than in the other types discussed here. Particularly in private institutions, the single-institution board has authority and responsibility for everything the university does, and it delegates responsibility and authority to various university officers, usually through the president or chancellor for the actual operation of the institution. These boards usually have complete fiduciary responsibility for the institution and exercise close supervision over financial and budget matters. At the same time, these boards differ substantially in the delegation of authority within the university. In some instances, they expect the president or chancellor to retain most of the authority and responsiin the central The majority of public research bility administration. In other cases, they expect universities operate within the campus chief executive to delegate that systems where several largely authority and responsibility to vice presidents, independently administered deans, and other university officers, while university campuses share retaining the supervisory role of ensuring the same board or multiple effective operation and managing and promotboards and commissions. ing institution-wide objectives such as fundraising. Very few public universities have this kind of clear relationship between the governing board and institutional management. Even when a public university has one board for a single campus institution, the politically selected board usually shares responsibility and authority, especially in financial and budgetary matters, with state-level bureaucracies, either in the form of higher education commissions or boards of education. Often, these higher-level organizations serve not as governing entities in relationship to the university’s board but as legislative or executive branch extensions to deal with fiscal policy and coordinate Page 7 issues related to the state’s support of higher education. While it is not always possible to make clear distinctions, many state-level organizations perform both functions and some are more intrusive than others in the operation of the university’s board. Public and private research universities with one governing board for a single institution may also have branch campuses. Although the dividing line that separates multi-campus institutions from single-campus institutions with branch campuses is none too clear, we think the distinction is worth making. When a university has branches that simply extend the university’s activities into other geographic locations, and the activities in these locations do not have independent academic personnel or curricular authority, then we consider them branch campuses and include the institution within the single-institution, single-board category. Historically, some single-campus, single-board institutions created branch campuses that later on acquired sufficient academic size and complexity to warrant more or less independence in their academic governance and operations. Usually in these cases, the defining distinction involves local campus control over promotion and tenure and often includes independent accreditation. In such instances, the single-campus, single-board institution becomes a multi-campus, single-board institution. The majority of public research universities operate within systems where several largely independently administered university campuses share the same board or multiple boards and commissions. Although the variety of structures and arrangements is impressive, most of these reflect two formative processes: • Consolidated systems usually emerge through the growth of branch campuses of a single university into a multiple-campus university system. Often distinguishable from multi-campus, single-board types, these consolidated systems have a systemlevel CEO and individual university CEOs but a governing board only for the system. • Coordinated systems result from a process that collects previously independent institutions into a structure governed by a single board. Typically, each institution has its own CEO, and these institutions do not manage multiple campuses. Often the coordinating board will oversee all state institutions of higher education including community and other two-year colleges. Although the origin of each of these types is of some interest, the levels of coordination and control exercised over the research institutions vary greatly within each of these types and the distribution of Governance Prototypes authority and responsibility changes over time. In both types, research campuses generally function in similar ways, as we discuss below. These multi-university systems themselves often belong to other governance structures, either reporting to a board of education or involved with coordinating agencies of every imaginable type. The powers and authority of these commissions and boards of education that exist outside the direct governance boards for the universities range from direct supervisory authority through coordinating authority to advisory functions. The following diagram illustrates the distribution of a group of universities defined by the criteria used for this publication’s Top American Research Universities. Note that all private universities fall into the first group of institutions with a single board for a single university. We divided the governance structures that apply to public research universities into three major categories (recognizing that this is a simplification of the full complexity of state system structures). The first group includes research universities that have single governing boards for each research university. Most of the universities in this group are in systems that have some form of statewide coordination, and some of the universities included here have branch campuses or medical branch campuses. The second group of universities has local boards for each university with powers derived from a single governing board. Most of the local boards have the authority to identify a campus chief executive and recommend the appointment to the governing board. These institutions usually have some form of statewide coordinating board or commission. The third and largest group of public universities reports to a single governing board along with other research universities. They have no local boards, although the systems of which they are a part usually work with a statewide coordinating board or commission. This group is large – in part because of the number of University of California institutions that qualify in the top category of research universities. This focus on public research universities should not obscure the fundamental distinction between public and private governance. In private universities, the single board not only focuses exclusively on the success of an individual university but also usually sees its role as supporting rather than controlling the institution. Public university boards, politically appointed or elected in most cases, usually serve to regulate the university on behalf of public constituencies. This fundamental difference in orientation and focus is the primary difference between public and private university governance. The Top American Research Universities Political Context Every state university, however it appears in a governance system taxonomy, is subject to the policy control of the state legislature and often to the policy objectives of the state’s executive branch. Legislatures can and do provide direct guidance on academic matters to state institutions, often overriding the presumed authority of institutional boards. Depending on the traditions and legal basis of the university’s Private university boards see charter (whether included within the their role as supporting their state’s constitution or created by legislative institutions; public university act), the form of this intervention may vary, but the state’s strength boards usually serve to in higher education issues comes in large regulate their universities on measure from the power to appropriate behalf of public constituencies. funds. When legal and administrative traditions place the university directly in the legislative process, this authority over academic matters can appear in explicit legislation specifying program content, graduation standards, and even detailed curricular matters. When legal traditions place the university outside of the direct legislative process, because the university is an artifact of the state constitution and not a creature of the legislature, the authority over academic issues may appear indirectly. The legislature can withhold appropriations until the university implements a desired goal or appropriates dollars restricted to a specific purpose or guided by a legislatively approved master plan. The multiple coordinating agencies that characterize many state higher education governance structures also serve to extend the legislature or governor’s influence over the operation of university programs. These considerations about legislative and executive branch intervention apply to all of the governing structures discussed here. Even private universities find themselves engaged in this conversation. Many states have coordinating commissions or other bureaucratic entities whose mandate includes some responsibility for rationalizing the educational delivery process of higher education, including not only public but also private, not-for-profit, and for-profit institutions. Laws in many states require all higher education institutions to receive permission from the Page 8 Governance Structures The Top American Research Universities Private and Public Institutions with More Than $20 Million in Federal Research Single Governing Board – Single Research University University may have branch campuses. Most Public universities have state-wide coordinating boards. Private universities may have a formal or informal relationship with a state-wide coordinating agency. Boston University Brandeis University Brown University California Institute of Technology Carnegie Mellon University Case Western Reserve University Charles R. Drew University of Medicine and Science Columbia University Cornell University Dartmouth University Duke University Emory University George Washington University Georgetown University Harvard University Howard University Johns Hopkins University Massachusetts Institute of Technology Michigan State University New Jersey Institute of Technology New York University Northeastern University Ohio State University - Columbus Princeton University Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute Rice University Rockefeller University Rush University Rutgers the State University of NJ New Brunswick Saint Louis University - St. Louis Stanford University Syracuse University Tufts University Tulane University University of Alaska - Fairbanks University of Chicago University of Cincinnati - Cincinnati University of Dayton University of Delaware University of Kentucky University of Miami University of Michigan - Ann Arbor University of Notre Dame University of Pennsylvania University of Rochester University of Southern California University of Vermont University of Virginia University of Washington - Seattle Vanderbilt University Virginia Commonwealth University Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University Wake Forest University Washington State University - Pullman Washington University Wayne State University Woods Hole Oceanographic Institution Yale University Yeshiva University Single Governing Board – Multiple Institutions with Local Trustee Boards Local Boards have delegated powers or legislatively defined powers. Most local boards recommend institution CEO. Most have state-wide coordinating boards. Auburn University - Auburn Clemson University Florida A&M University Florida State University North Carolina State University Pennsylvania State University University Park University at Albany University at Buffalo University at Stony Brook University of Florida University of North Carolina Chapel Hill University of Pittsburgh - Pittsburgh University South Carolina - Columbia University of South Florida University of Utah Utah State University Single Governing Board – Multiple Institutions with No Local Board Most have state-wide coordinating boards. Arizona State University - Tempe Colorado State University Georgia Institute of Technology Indiana University - Bloomington Indiana University - Purdue University Indianapolis Iowa State University Kansas State University Louisiana State University - Baton Rouge Mississippi State University Montana State University - Bozeman New Mexico State University - Las Cruces Oklahoma State University - Stillwater Oregon State University Purdue University - West Lafayette Temple University Texas A&M University University of Alabama - Birmingham University of Alabama - Huntsville Page 9 University of Arizona University of California - Berkeley University of California - Davis University of California - Irvine University of California - Los Angeles University of California - San Diego University of California - Santa Barbara University of California - Santa Cruz University of Colorado - Boulder University of Connecticut - Storrs University of Georgia University of Hawaii - Manoa University of Houston - University Park University of Idaho University of Illinois - Chicago University of Illinois - Urbana-Champaign University of Iowa University of Kansas - Lawrence University of Maryland - College Park University of Massachusetts - Amherst University of of Minnesota Twin Cities University of Missouri - Columbia University of Nebraska - Lincoln University of Nevada - Reno University of New Hampshire Durham University of of New Mexico Albuquerque University of Oklahoma - Norman University of Oregon University of Puerto Rico - Mayaguez University of Rhode Island - Kingston University of Tennessee - Knoxville University of Texas - Austin University of Wisconsin - Madison West Virginia University Political Context state before offering educational services. States have tuition support programs that give modest but significant financial grants to private institutions for enrolled in-state students. The provision of this funding carries with it the opportunity for the state to assert some influence over the academic behavior of private institutions. This influence is less directive and less comprehensive than the relationship between the state and its public institutions, but nonetheless makes the state’s higher education policy goals relevant to private institutions. Politics is a source of most public university existence. The state, on behalf of the people, creates the institutions, provides significant portions of revenue, and regulates institutional behavior. State systems of governance and coordination act as agents of the state’s political authority and regulate, direct, and control universities in response to the political process. This power flows clearly and directly from public ownership of the state university, and the trustees (regents, board of education members) have an obligation to manage the institutions on behalf of the people as directed by state officials. Some of this may seem obvious, but it deserves emphasis because it is in this role that public university or university system trustees differ most significantly from their private university counterparts. The private university board owns the university directly and answers to the public primarily in terms of its fiduciary responsibility. The private university board focuses almost exclusively on the effort to fund and enhance university performance as defined by the board and the institution. It works on behalf of the institution, not on behalf of outside political constituencies. While the private board may take social needs, public obligations, and alumni and citizen concerns into consideration, it does not have a formal and direct obligation to direct the university to meet these concerns. The private board aligns its efforts with the interests of the institution it supervises. Indeed, one of the primary considerations for membership on a private university board is a commitment to the university’s mission, frequently expressed through substantial philanthropy. This difference in perspective explains why public university presidents, chancellors, chief financial officers, and other top executives often feel as if they have arrived in heaven when they move from managing a public institution to managing a private institution. The political imperatives for public university governance appear clearly to many political and bureaucratic leaders within the various states, and the members of these boards gain their posts usually by political means. Nonetheless, universities themselves are politi- The Top American Research Universities cal entities that can and do act independently in their own self-interest. Public universities have alumni and local and regional support groups. They serve many constituencies of high political value in their states. Public research Public universities themselves universities have multiple sources of revenue in addiare political entities that can tion to state dollars, and most universities of any and do act independently in distinction provide the state with services funded their self-interest through from these non-state resources. Whether in teaching, research, ecoalumni and local and nomic development, or various forms of service, regional support groups. the research university generates a substantial proportion of the revenue it spends. As a result, states simply cannot dispose of universities as political imperatives of the moment might indicate. If a proposed political change appears dangerous to the university, the institution will mobilize its forces to resist that change even when its politically appointed governance system may not concur. Often the university is remarkably successful in defeating the substance, if not necessarily the form, of political intervention. In this political context, the governance system finds itself in a conflict. While in theory the trustees, boards, or other direct governance organizations serve the state and are responsible to the state for the operation of the universities, they also often assume the values and aspirations of the research institutions they regulate. A public board enhances its identification with the institution’s objectives when it supervises only one institution. Political agenda are more significant when the board supervises multiple institutions. The governor may appoint the trustees, for example, but if the governor’s agenda appears to threaten the universities’ aspirations, and if the universities and their alumni can make this case persuasively, these politically appointed boards may resist the changes identified as essential by the legislature, governor, or state bureaucracy. In this intermediary role, the trustees or other public governance systems may find themselves sometimes on the side of enforcing the expectations of elected and appointed state officials and, at other times, on the side of resisting these expectations. On occasion, the governance system’s lack of responsiveness to the state political agenda will lead to a reorganization of higher education in order to impose the state’s will more effectively. Page 10 This kind of reorganization falls into two categories. States can impose a higher level of control on existing institutional governance structures by creating higher education coordinating, budgetary, or policy commissions, or by redistributing power and authority among the various levels of the state higher education governance system. These a filtering bureaucraWhen coordinating interpose cy responsible to legislatures or governors that reduces the mechanisms for aligning effectiveness of institutions and their governing boards in takpublic universities with ing institutional agenda directly to the political process. current political objectives Coordinating commissions vary in their effectiveness depending fail, states often change on the powers awarded them by the legislature or governor on their ability to impose the organization of the and their determinations over the of the governing higher education system. aspirations boards of the individual institutions or groups of institutions in the state. If the legislature and governor permit the institutional or system boards to carry their agenda directly to the political process and fail to assert the authority of the coordinating board, commission, or agency, then the coordinating unit will become just another bureaucratic but mostly ineffective voice in the crowd. When coordinating commissions and other mechanisms for aligning the institutions with a state’s current political objectives fail to perform adequately, states may change the organization of the state higher education system either completely or substantially. They can consolidate institutions into a single system or multiple systems with direct controlling bureaucracies headed by politically appointed chief executives or boards. They can impose a high-level board with the authority to control the lower-level governance boards for the individual institutions or groups of institutions, and they can put particular educational objectives into law. While these changes sometimes respond to perceived or real problems of effectiveness and efficiency in the higher education system, at other times they respond to the needs of the political actors who seek innovation and change as part of a wider state agenda. Of particular interest in this conversation is the role of technocratic elites at various levels of the public higher education system in most states. The technocrats often staff legislative committees concerned with the funding and operation of higher education, serve in the governor’s or other executive branch offices that Page 11 deal with educational budget issues, and serve on the staffs of coordinating commissions. Such individuals have considerable expertise about university funding, curricular trends, student access, and other matters essential to the successful delivery of higher education to the people of the state. Often they have strong personal opinions about how universities should operate. Although they are not part of the direct institutional governance through its administrative shell, they nonetheless have significant influence because they control the details of the political processes at different levels above the quality engine and often become key actors in determining and implementing state policies that affect public research universities. The technocrats sometimes support the aspirations of research universities, but often their values lead them to prefer to support large-scale generic undergraduate education. The effort of managing this particular set of technocratic actors constitutes one of the important tasks of the staff of individual university shell organizations. In every state – whatever the formal organization of higher education governance – the political culture and, in particular, the location of power within state government determine how the system functions. If power is concentrated in the hands of the governor, then the governor will drive state higher education policy and funding. If power resides in the hands of longterm legislative leadership, then legislators will drive higher education. If state government shares or disperses power widely within its agencies and term limits diminish the power of legislative leadership, then technocratic staff and multiple-party negotiations may characterize higher education governance. No formal statement of organizational structure adequately captures public higher education governance without a parallel understanding of how the formal structure relates to the actual distribution of political power within state government. Purpose and Functions of Governance Practically every state develops a strategic vision for its higher education system, whether expressed in the form of a master plan or a mission statement. The relevance of these strategic perspectives to state funding and system organization varies greatly, and many strategic plans remain as statements of intent rather than directives for action. A much more commonly pursued goal of statewide coordination of higher education is to restrain costs and reduce program duplication to a minimum. Captivated by the organizational notions current in American business, where consoli- Purpose and Functions of Governance dation, efficiency, and economies of scale appear ascendant, state legislators and governors hope to achieve similar results by imposing large-scale organizational models on the rapidly proliferating campuses dependent on state funding. While each state develops a pattern for distributing authority and responsibility for higher education to the various components of its higher education governance system, some common elements appear in every state. Money underlies much of this conversation. States recognize the rapidly increasing cost of higher education resulting from the growing percentage of their population attending college after World War II, and especially after 1960, accompanied by an increase in the complexity and sophistication of public higher education institutions. Much of the coordination and governance effort focuses on controlling and managing costs. Legislators, for example, often find it difficult to evaluate competing requests from the many institutions in their states. Legislative and executive leadership seeks mechanisms to insulate legislators from decisions on the relative merit of budget requests from individual institutions. The higher education coordinating structure appears attractive in many states because it promises an expert-driven structure for evaluating institutional legislative budget requests. While in many cases legislators reduce, expand, or otherwise change the consolidated budget requests received from the coordinating agencies or governance systems, they nonetheless start from a unified presentation. Most importantly, this arrangement provides a mechanism that insulates legislators from the bad news of denying budget requests and leaves them free to add good things to the higher education budget for their constituencies if funding and political forces make this possible. The appointed higher education governance and coordination system delivers most of the bad news, and the elected legislators deliver most of the good news. In some states, this works well; in others, the governance system can become an antagonist of the legislature and executive branch, asking for much more than the state can afford and then blaming the legislature or the governor when funds fail to materialize. When this behavior grows too intense, states reorganize or restructure the governance system. In the drive for efficiency and effectiveness, and again drawing on corporate models, states use the higher education governance system to achieve some measure of what they call accountability. Accountability is a term of art in higher education, The Top American Research Universities especially public higher education. From the state’s point of view, accountability is a process for measuring the effectiveness of higher education institutions principally in terms of their ability to produce functional graduates at low cost. While disguised by a wide range of subjective qualitative rhetoric, the driver of accountability is efficiency. State actors outside higher education, and many within, believe colleges and universities have little interest in effectiveness or efficiency. Universities have few standardized measures of efficiency and no equivalent to business-like profit statements or return on investment calculations. The accountability process presumes to imitate these business indicators with some academic equivalent. Statewide governance systems, individual institutions, and independent state agencies all develop measures of accountability. Legislators and governors hope these will provide reasonable guidance for standards of institutional effectiveness and for public investment decisions about higher education needs. The results of the accountability movement have not realized the high hopes of many, but most statewide governance systems have some form of accountability program nonetheless. Another key regulatory purpose is mission differentiation and program approval. Institutional mission differentiation appears in the formal master plans approved by most states or through historically determined or cooperative mission assignments as No organizational structure apply in other states. Many states, such as adequately explains public Florida, illustrate the difficulty of instituhigher education governance tion-specific mission differentiation even within single-board, without a parallel multiple-university environments. understanding of the actual Although that state’s board of regents distribution of political power attempted to specify particular missions for within state government. its individual institutions at the time of their creation, over the years the power of local politics overwhelmed board policies as local constituencies mobilized to support mission expansion. Recent reorganization of higher education in Florida created the opportunity for community colleges to break the four-year degree barrier, a formerly substantial dividing marker for higher education mission differentiation. Page 12 Almost every state controls program approval to restrain local-campus constituency enthusiasm for duplicating prestige programs that exist elsewhere in the state. Medical schools, engineering programs, art and music programs, professional schools in law, medicine, public health, and veterinary medicine, architecture schools – these and many other specialties come at a high price although they bring prestige. Statewide program review and approval attempts to determine whether the state actually needs an additional program or advanced degrees or whether an existing program could meet the demand. States vary widely in their ability to contain program expansion and proliferation, as the creation of expensive prestige programs or advanced degrees is often a token of political effectiveness for the local legislative delegation. States especially worry about high-cost programs such as medical schools. Although system organizations do not always prevent the proliferation of medical some systems treat States vary widely in their schools, the medical enterprise as a separately adminability to contain program distinct, istered entity. In such places, the medical enterproliferation, as the creation prise becomes a separate campus, geographically of expensive prestige programs apart from either the flagship institution or other is often a token of local major campuses. Sometimes the medical political effectiveness. campus reports to the flagship campus, even if it is not closely connected to it in any organic way; at other times the system treats the medical campus as a stand-alone institution reporting directly to the system executive and board. These arrangements respond to legislative and institutional history that create opportunities in locations separate from the main campus, or they may serve to resolve conflicts of authority and responsibility by creating a separate relationship for the medical campus. Whatever the origin, the separate campus for a medical center changes the dynamics of relationships between the medical research program and the research activities on the system’s research campuses. When the medical center is part of a research campus, it has a much greater impact on the research activities of other faculty in related and allied disciplines. State systems usually address a variety of academic standards issues. Admissions processes and transferability of credit among institutions within the state usually appear on the system agenda. Admissions Page 13 issues reflect the implementation of the state’s student access imperative of affording an opportunity for higher education to the widest possible state audience. Sometimes admission issues include limits on out-ofstate students or establishment of minimum standards of entry, even when the admissions process itself is a local, institution-by-institution concern. Elsewhere, university systems operate common admissions processes for every institution, using standard forms and data, and standard criteria. In those systems, students usually have the option of selecting their preferred campus; the better their admission credentials, the better their chance of admission to the campus of their choice. State systems also specify other common characteristics of the admissions process, most recently in terms of the acceptability of affirmative action programs but also including special financial aid grants and exceptions for student-athletes, musicians, artists, alumni children, or donor relatives. Statewide requirements about the transferability of credit from one state institution to another (community college to college or university, and between colleges and universities within the state) also reflect the state’s commitment to institutional mission differentiation. If different colleges have different missions and different programs, students will often take some part of a program at institutions in one place and the specialized courses at another institution that has the mission to provide the special program, major, or degree. For this to work efficiently, student academic credits earned at one state college or university must transfer to every other in the state. Much effort in many states is devoted to ensuring this transferability, from transfer requirements to common course numbering systems that guarantee the course equivalency at all state higher education institutions. Because institutions vary in the quality of their student bodies and faculty, and in the range and extent of their academic resources, colleges and their faculty often resist these standardizing efforts. Sometimes they succeed; most often they do not. Almost all states have a sharp distinction between community colleges that provide the first two years of the traditional four-year degree and colleges or universities that provide all four years as well as advanced degrees. However, linkage between the community college and the four-year institution varies from explicit formal linkages such as those in Florida to less comprehensive or restrictive transfer rules and agreements that apply in other states. Whatever the governance model, systems all focus on generating revenue. In public university contexts, the governance systems of boards and commissions Purpose and Functions of Governance focus primarily on the funding that comes through the political process at the state level. Systems may share this function with people and organizations located at the individual campuses, but they generally assume the primary responsibility to deal with the state on issues of budget and finance. Depending on allocation of authority and responsibility to campuses, system officers also may control or participate in private fundraising, commercialization of intellectual property, and operation of revenue-generating enterprises such as distance education or economic development programs. In these activities, however, the system usually serves as the agent for campus-based, faculty-created content. In fund-raising, for example, few donors give to a system of higher education. Most give to a campus, and even more specifically to an individual school, college, or program. Systems can provide a range of support to campus fund-raising that enhances the ability of colleges, departments, and campuses to attract gifts. The most effective support comes from matching programs that usually appear as system-wide, state-funded efforts. The details of these programs vary, including direct dollar-for-dollar matches at ratios of 1 to 1 or, more commonly, some proportion of the gift dollar matched by state funds. Other programs exist where the system uses state funds to match the anticipated income from the endowment gift but does not transfer state dollars into the endowment. Systems also supply other less visible, but often important, support. They can delegate authority and responsibility for fund-raising to campuses, increasing the effectiveness of fund-raising activities, or they can authorize the creation of campus-based foundations that give donors a clear sense of confidence that their gifts will stay at the campus and serve designated purposes. Some state systems deposit foundation money in state accounts, but most give the campus foundation the authority and responsibility for managing the endowment. Statewide systems generally support campusbased capital campaigns and encourage their success. In their role as revenue generators, systems often serve to combine campus resources when a revenue opportunity appears that does not fall fully within the mission of a single campus. In such a role, the system can encourage or force campuses to cooperate, combine resources, and deliver services. Sometimes campuses defend a local self-interest and decline to cooperate in statewide multi-campus activities. The system can exercise its authority to force cooperation and collaboration. The system can also serve as a supervising entity for large-scale research programs The Top American Research Universities that fall outside the direct mission of the campus, require separate funding, or need state funding that the system can guarantee. Independent national research laboratories, for example, often exist outside the direct control of a campus reporting to a systemlevel governance entity, although drawing on the intellectual strength of the campus’ guilds for their work and their academic prestige. Imperative of Statewide Governance The needs of the state, expressed in political terms through the actions of legislatures, elected executive branch officials, and permanent state bureaucracies, result in an intervention in the affairs of the public research university, delivered through the intermediary of the university’s governance system. If efficiency and effectiveness become an issue, states create or mandate accountability programs loaded with good intentions but usually without significant Public university systems, effect. If access becomes an issue, states determine the rather than individual distribution of students to institutions, offer incentives campuses, assume primary to expand existing institutions, create new ones, and responsibility for dealing evaluate competing plans for providing access. If cost with the state on budget becomes a significant issue – and it always does, states can and finance. use the governance system to shorten the time to degree, reduce the expense of research faculty, limit the personnel costs of teaching, and expand the lowest cost options for undergraduate education. If economic development becomes a priority, states can review technology transfer programs, encourage the licensing of technology to in-state corporations, and expect increased engagement of university people in local or statewide economic development. These imperatives, expressed in as many forms and with as many variations as there are states, often lead to frustration as research universities fail to respond to the perhaps unrealistic expectations of the political and bureaucratic leadership. While this sometimes prompts specific legislative intervention in the academic process, more often it produces reorganization and reconfiguration of the higher education system with stronger hierarchical structure. This enthusiasm for changing the organization usually responds to a belief that public higher education fails to meet political objectives because of a failure of central control, direction, and authority. Page 14 Relationship of Governance to Research University Competitiveness In the conversation about governance, the proponents of particular organizational models or reorganization schemes usually assert that one or another structure is clearly superior for quality higher education. While it is relatively easy to find dysfunctional behavior in complex public higher education systems attempting to coordinate and manage highly diverse institutions with multiple and differing missions, it is much more difficult to find ideal types adaptable to the many different state environments. What works in California does not translate to New York. What proves successful in Indiana does not have a future in Florida. What appears successful in Michigan has no currency in Louisiana. Each of these models is a political not an educational artifact, and it responds to the local political concerns of the state it serves. The multiple variations on the basic organizational models described above that appear in different It is difficult to find ideal types states at different times provide eloquent testiof public higher education mony to the locally adaptive character of systems. Each is a political public university system organization. artifact designed to respond to The impact of statewide governance the local concerns of its state. structures on the functioning of individual institutions varies. For those institutions primarily focused on the production of undergraduates for immediate employment after graduation, the form, organization, and supervision of statewide governance boards and local institutional boards have a significant impact on university behavior. For research universities, however, the impact of these governance mechanisms is much less. The undergraduate-producing institution often has a much higher percentage of its budget derived from state-controlled resources than the research university. The faculty, staff, and students of these primarily undergraduate colleges and universities serve a predominantly regional or, at most, statewide constituency. Research universities, however, focus on competitiveness with their national peers and produce graduates for a national marketplace. As a result, changes in statewide governance often have a much greater impact on predominantly undergraduate institutions than they do on research universities, even within the same system. Page 15 Research campuses in complex governance systems often have the best students, the best faculty, and the most extensive facilities of any higher education institution in the state. Compared to their teaching-focused counterparts, they have more alumni support, provide more service to the state, and have more prestige. Their financial requirements are high because they tend to have high-cost programs, professional schools, and other facilities that are critically important for the success of many state economic development initiatives. When a state applies accountability mechanisms in an attempt to measure and reward effectiveness, research universities usually meet or exceed the targets set for all state universities. They have the best students, residential campuses, strong student services programs, and with these advantages, they usually meet graduation, retention, and enrollment targets. They have many unique programs and can always demonstrate unique contributions to the state. Their research strength leads to significant economic return to the state from employment, economic development programs, spin-off industries, and technical assistance to state agencies and private enterprise. A research university with a research-oriented medical school and affiliated hospital can always demonstrate a major contribution to the state’s health care, especially for indigent and uninsured patients. All of this makes statewide governance an important issue – but not a controlling factor – for public research universities. Indeed, in many cases, much of the statewide governance activity – of vital interest to those who work in the university’s shell organizations – has little direct impact on faculty work. Although salary issues, arguments about faculty rights, union rules, credit transfer regulations, curricular controls, and program approvals may depend on the statewide governance system for answers, the issues themselves and the state’s responses to them do not appear to depend much on the form of governance. If we look at all the universities with more than $20 million in federal expenditures in 1999, and arrange them by type of governance, we can see that they fall into two obvious groups. The private universities all have single boards, and the advantage of their organization derives primarily, we believe, from the private board’s role in support of the institution. The second group includes all public universities. Within each of the three general types identified here, we find highly competitive institutions as well as those with less success. Of those with a single board for a single institution, just under half have at least one of our measures in the top 25 among public universities. Relationship of Governance to Competitiveness Public Research Institutions by Governance Type and Number of Measures in the Top 25 Just over half have no measure in the top 25. Of those with a single board governing multiple institutions and the institutions with a local board, half have at least one measure in the top 25 and half have no measure in the top 25. Finally, of those with a single governing board over multiple institutions and no local board, again, half have at least one measure in the top 25 and half do not. These data indicate that highly competitive public universities and those significantly less competitive work within all types of governance systems. Governance structure, in our view, is not a critical dimension of public research university success. This conclusion requires a tight focus. Public university systems have many functions and serve many purposes in the political life of states. Systems often take on lives of their own, maximize advantages that they find significant for their executives, board members, and other personnel, and project themselves into local and national political and academic space to enhance their importance. From our perspective on and experience with the competitive success of research universities, however, the particular organization of a university system is much less important than other characteristics of the environment in which the research campus exists. Delegated authority for most academic and administrative decision to the campus, strong support for quality and productivity, and effective research administration all contribute to the success of highly competitive institutions. The same system at some times may support and at other times inhibit the aspirations of the research campus. These different outcomes depend not on the structure of the The Top American Research Universities organization but on the quality and perspectives of the people who direct the system. If those people share the aspirations of the research university, they can help it succeed. If they seek other goals, usually related to local or state political agenda or personal career advancement, they may see the national perspective of the research university as an obstacle to their local ambitions and inhibit the institution’s research success. Other characteristics than organizational form make more of a difference. Universities whose states provide more money have a relative advantage in the competition for quality than those whose states provide less. Money matters for the support of research and the acquisition of quality students in all universities. While the complexity and variety of institutional arrangements make strong statements about the causes of research university success rather speculative, we nonetheless think that the following represent reasonable starting points for discussion. As our model suggests and as the relationship between financial support and performance discussed below appears to indicate, public and private research universities with strong financial support do well – no matter what organizational model governs them. It is difficult to know whether states with clear mission differentiation for their institutions or systems such as California and North Carolina succeed because of the differentiation or whether the clarity in missions is the result of long state traditions that govern investment in high-quality universities. Nonetheless, public research universities in states with clear mission differentiation separating research-intensive and teaching-intensive institutions generally appear to compete more successfully than in Page 16 those in states where differentiation is ambiguous. Following our hypothesis that money matters, we would expect public research universities in states that enjoy a long tradition of investment in and appreciation for national quality in research and students to compete better because of their stronger financial support than similar institutions in states that focus primarily on undergraduate Universities whose states access and degree generation. From the perspective of provide more money have a system officers, however, the view of university success relative advantage in the may well appear differently than it does from the competition for quality. research campus. The university system is a super shell entity removed from the teaching and research work of academic life. Some university systems acquire derived assets such as distance education enterprises, continuing education, and economic development, but, even so, they depend on the work of the faculty guilds in the core of each of the system campuses for their legitimacy and success. Given the remarkable diversity of organization and structure, the stability and familiarity of the internal organization of the research university – what we call the academic core – is remarkable. Whatever the structure of the administrative shell and whatever the higher-level organization of systems or statewide governance, every research university, at the level of the guilds where the teaching and research work is done and where the curriculum is defined and delivered, appears similar and functions in almost identical ways. Indeed, from the perspective of the academic core of the university, most of the conversation that occupies the attention of political actors at the university shell and governance system, and the legislative and executive branches, appears almost irrelevant. In the end, what matters for the faculty and students is the teaching and research of the academic guilds, activities regulated by a range of accrediting agencies for teaching, degrees, and research in many professional fields, and by national guild-based peer review for research publication and grants. If a state transforms its entire higher education organization, reconstitutes individual universities into systems with a single board and a single chief executive on behalf of the system, the faculty and students on each campus will continue as before and do almost exactly the same things in the same ways and using the same standards. If the new system provides more money, they will do better perhaps. If the coordination changes transfer requirements and Page 17 similar student-related conditions, some segments of the institution may see an impact but, for the most part, the academic core in public research universities functions in the same way, whatever the statewide organization. Not so in the institution’s administrative shell, where changes in system organization have a profound effect on the balance of power, authority, opportunity, career possibilities, and administrative functions. With consolidation into systems, individual shell officials from presidents or chancellors to registrars, from financial affairs officers to police departments, all find themselves dealing with new relationships. In some cases, they acquire new authority if the change decentralizes functions; in other cases, they lose authority if the change centralizes functions. In either case, the jobs of the shell participants change with the governance structure. For this reason, debates over system changes often engage shell actors directly and they become major participants in the controversies that always surround major political restructuring of state university governance. While forms of organization vary within state systems, the actual architecture of the system appears to us much less important than the distribution of authority and responsibility throughout the system. In reviewing the details of delegated authority for a number of highly competitive institutions within complex systems, the pattern of delegating substantially all academic and administrative authority to the campus is evident. The implications of an organizational change depend on the details of the resulting arrangements and delegations of authority, and the impact of any change will vary depending on the capabilities and needs of each campus. The success of any particular university system also depends as much on the quality of the governing organization’s leadership as it does on the precise organization. A governance structure with strong and effective leadership can help the research university succeed; the same structure with weak leadership can inhibit success. Cost, Complexity, Regulation, and Money Our principal concern in these reports is to understand the competition that defines the American research university. We have identified some of the measurable areas of competition for the scarce resources that define research university success, and we have looked at some of the characteristics of universities that influence this competition. We have found that the size of an institution helps explain at least some part of the competitive research success of Cost, Complexity, Regulation, and Money public, but not private, universities, and we have seen that the presence of a research-intensive medical faculty is a significant asset in this competition, even if the mere existence of a medical school is not. We have noted that public research universities dominate the competition for federal research dollars, although some private universities continue to compete exceptionally well. The examination of the differences between public and private research institutions led us to reconsider our original notion that we could approach the analysis of competition among research universities by looking at public and private universities separately. The competitive model we found shows public and private research universities competing in remarkably similar ways for students and faculty, federal grants and contracts, and private resources. As a result, after the first year, we redesigned our Top American Research Universities to present public and private universities together, although we continue to offer separate presentations to maintain consistency with the first report and to support our colleagues who found the data useful when displayed by institutional control. In this review of institutional organization, in which we anticipated identifying some other elements distinguishing public from private institutions, we have two tentative conclusions. • First, the impact of large-scale organizational structures in the public sector does not appear to have a major effect on the competition for research or for high-quality students in major research universities. While differences surely exist between public and private undergraduate programs, most public research universities find ways to compete for the best students and to deliver excellent undergraduate results in every organizational model we reviewed. However, the success of public universities in the student competition is somewhat obscured by the wide range in student quality in most of the large, high-quality public institutions. The students recruited into public university honors programs, for example, have SAT scores and other quality indicators equivalent to those of the highly competitive private universities. • Second, these often elaborate and hierarchical public organizational structures within which public research universities function clearly create inefficiencies, duplicate work, and generate high administrative costs compared to the relatively lean and flat structures that govern private institutions. The Top American Research Universities Why then, do public universities perform so well in the competition for the scarce resources that define research university success? The answer is not all that complicated. It is the money. Understanding university money is complicated by the accounting standards followed by public and private universities (which use different standards) and by the organizational differences among public universities (which define expenses and The contribution of income in different organizations or at different levels of the state tax dollars to state bureaucracy). Nonetheless, it is our belief that the contribupublic research universition of state tax dollars to public research universities more than compensates for the added cost ties more than compenand inefficiency that are a consequence of complicated public sates for the added cost governance structures. In our data, we include two and inefficiency that are items of institutional resources: endowment assets and annual a consequence of comgiving. These two items provide an indicator of how well univerplicated public goversities (and their related foundations) compete in the private nance systems. marketplace for gifts in support of student and research quality. In these data we easily see that private universities often have significantly higher totals than their public counterparts. In 2001, among the research universities in our study (those with more than $20 million in federal research expenditures), the private institutions’ median endowment at $1.1 billion is four times greater than the public universities’ endowment of $250 million. Their annual giving shows a median of $94.8 million for privates and $45.0 million for publics. However, because institutional resources are so critical to the ability of research universities to compete, we are not satisfied with these indicators. Resources represent a complicated notion for universities. In this conversation, we draw on the work of the Williams Center directed by Gordon Winston and the useful article by Bradburd and Mann published in 1993, both cited below. We have explored the possibility of identifying all the assets and obligations of an institution and then, by various means, translating these assets less obligations into an index of institutional wealth. This is not easy to do, as the papers of the Williams Center and the Bradburd and Mann article show – not only due to accounting rules that do not allow clear distinctions but also because Page 18 publics present their financials by fund group while private universities do not. In the case of private practices do not lend universities, current accounting rules permit capture of the entire themselves to a clear enterprise; with public universities, only the operating budget is understanding of the as easily accessed. The Governmental Accounting institution’s total Standards Board (GASB) has established a new reporting model resources. that will require all universities, both public and private, to report on an entity-wide basis in their financial statements by fiscal year 2002. In addition, public universities have many different methods of holding and managing assets. Buildings and grounds, debt, retirement accounts, and similar elements of a public university’s total assets appear in different places for different institutions and systems. In some states, plant belongs to the state and is accounted for as a part of the state’s assets. Retirement fund balances and large obligations such as worker’s compensation or liability and property insurance can belong to the state and not the university. Debt may be located at a university campus, consolidated for many universities at a system office, or held by the state itself. The variety and significance of these different methods of managing public money for universities are exceptional. In addition, universities, public and private, hold other kinds of assets in different ways. Medical practice plans, hospital assets and budgets, athletic association funds, private endowment balances and income, and similar sources of funds can appear inside the university’s accounting system or within other entities. Although, in theory, detailed work with state and institutional accounts might permit a resolution of some of these problems, as a practical matter we do not believe we have the tools yet to construct a clear, institution-to-institution comparison of total assets. Accounting rules and Endowment-Equivalent Nonetheless, money matters. In exploring the trade-off between complexity and money that is part of the explanation for public research university success in the competition with private universities, we developed a rough sketch of the comparative endowment and endowment-equivalent resources available to public and private research universities. To do this, we drew our inspiration from a notion originally proposed by Bradburd and Mann (1993). Looking only at Page 19 research universities, we start with their 1999 endowment assets at market value. Then, we take their annual giving for 1999 and convert this to an endowment-equivalent. By endowment-equivalent, we mean the amount of endowment that would be required to generate this annual giving income stream. We assume an endowment payout of 4.5%, which represents the generally accepted and widely used 5% spending formula calculated upon a moving three-year (or 12-quarter) average. We derived this estimate from the methodology used by Moody’s Investors Service for evaluating the creditworthiness of colleges and universities. Thus, to get the endowment-equivalent of the annual giving stream, we take annual giving and divide it by 0.045. Using the same methodology, we convert the state appropriation into an endowment-equivalent. This is obviously a much more important element for public than for private universities, but many private institutions have state subsidies of various kinds. The final income stream we identify is gross tuition and fees. Although tuition is widely discounted through institutional financial aid, our interest is in the potential endowment-equivalent resources available to the university, and so for this purpose we use the gross tuition and fees. We also convert this income stream into an endowment-equivalent. To get the total endowment-equivalent for private and public universities we add these items: • regular endowment • annual giving endowment-equivalent • state appropriation endowment-equivalent • tuition and fees endowment-equivalent These calculations do not provide a total for all university assets that generate income or value for the university. Accounting rules and practices for universities, as we have mentioned before, do not lend themselves to a clear understanding of the institution’s total resources. Especially for public universities, many elements of the university’s total resources may not even appear on the university’s financial statements. For example, in some states, the state pays debt service and carries this expenditure on the state’s accounts, not the universities’. As a result, the university has the use of more resources than appear on its statements because the institutional financial reports understate the institution’s income by the amount of debt service paid on its behalf by the state. Not all resources held in private foundations on behalf of the institution or in various auxiliaries that support the institution appear in uni- Endowment-Equivalent versity reports. When universities are part of complex systems as described previously, the distribution of the costs and benefits of the system may not appear in ways easily attributable to the university benefited or charged. All of this recommends significant caution when using the data we develop and present here. The purpose of the exercise is to assess in a general way the relative economic strength of public and private research universities, not to present a comprehensive and complete analysis of institutional assets and liabilities, or to compare individual institutions. Our interest in a general comparison of public and private institutions is to show how public universities, by virtue of the constant support provided by their state governments from tax revenues, often have comparable financial resources to invest in quality, compared to private universities with apparently large endowments. This is a conservative approach because most of the errors that come from the inability to deal with capital expenses reduce the apparent resources of the public universities. That is, they have more to work with than we have captured here. If we can show that the public institutions appear to have as much or more in financial resources than many of their private counterparts, we are likely underestimating the public institution’s advantage. Differences in scale among universities suggest another adjustment. Some of the apparent financial strength of the public institution may be deceptive because it reflects the cost of large-scale undergraduate instruction. This is an important function of public universities. It is not, however, one of the competitive issues for research universities who compete for student quality and faculty research productivity. To adjust for this factor of scale, we also present the data after deducting the endowment-equivalent supporting basic instruction. We use $7,000 as the basic cost for an undergraduate FTE, $8,750 for a graduate FTE, and $20,000 for a professional school FTE. The undergraduate baseline cost comes from the NACUBO Cost of College Study (2002), using the 10th percentile for four-year public universities and estimating graduate education at 1.25 times the baseline cost of undergraduate instruction. The estimate for the baseline cost of a professional student FTE is more tentative than the others used here. Some professional programs in medicine and veterinary medicine have very high costs; we estimate others, such as law, at much lower cost. Our estimate of $20,000 is our best approximation of a baseline cost for professional school FTEs. The following graphs plot the total endowmentequivalent for private and public universities in rank The Top American Research Universities order. As we showed in previous publications, about twice as many public institutions meet the minimum of $20 million in federal research expenditures as private universities. This reflects the investment of state revenue in public universities that has allowed them to build sufficient capacity to compete successfully against their private counterparts. The graph helps us understand the basis for the emergence of the researchintensive public universities. In terms of total endowment-equivalent, before adjusting for the factor of enrollment, the graph shows that public universities rank with private universities in terms of the resources measured here at every level. This result, however, likely overstates the impact of public university resources from Public funding of public state appropriations for large undergraduate enrollments. institutions more than If we then adjust downward the total endowment-equivalent compensates for the to account for the extra income public universities get as a result higher endowments of of their larger enrollments funded with state dollars and tuition and fees, the pattern changes private universities. slightly. While public universities remain competitive in every category with their private counterparts, the private institutions in the top 20 outnumber the publics. Indeed, a disproportionately smaller number in the last two groups balances the disproportionately larger number of private universities in this top group. Insofar as success in the competition for quality requires substantial resources, the data reflect the public institution’s ability to acquire the necessary funds. Public funding of public institutions more than compensates for the higher endowments of private universities. Although this adjusted total compensates for different levels of student enrollment between public and private universities, it also compensates for different levels of enrollment within the two control groups. This has the effect of changing the order of private and public universities between their total endowmentequivalent rank and their enrollment-adjusted total endowment-equivalent rank. These changes are not particularly significant, however, as the r-square between the rankings on the adjusted vs. the nonadjusted total endowment-equivalent is 0.95 regardless of ownership. In other words, the rank order for both publics and privates changes very little with the adjustment for size. Page 20 Total Endowment-Equivalent Universities with More Than $20 Million in Federal Research in Rank Order While these calculations do not give us a full picture of the total resources available to public and private institutions, they suggest that public universities have substantial revenues equivalent to or exceeding those of their private counterparts for investment in support of those elements of quality they identify as most important. Some of this revenue, as discussed in detail in the Williams Center papers, supports subsidies for educational quality expressed both in the form of tuition discounting and added enhancements to the quality (and expense) of undergraduate education. The other investments support the added costs of high-quality research. As we discussed in more detail in the The Top American Research Universities (2001), academic research requires extensive support from university funds because grants, contracts, and other forms of external support do not pay the full cost of the research produced. This additional support, like the subsidies and enhancements for high-quality undergraduate education, comes primarily from endowment income or, in our model, from the total endowment-equivalent income generated by public and private institutions. Given the substantial resources available to public institutions, as identified in this discussion, it is not surprising to find so many public universities competing successfully against private universities both for high-quality students and for research grants and contracts. Only in the top category do more private universities have enrollment-adjusted total endowmentequivalent resources than public institutions. More Page 21 detailed research may provide us with a clearer indication of this public university strength in the competition for academic quality, but our example here probably underestimates the public institution’s competitive advantage in supporting the competition for institutional quality among research universities. We have reviewed a few of the benefits that some, but not all, public institutions enjoy that do not always appear in public university accounts. In addition, we should note that these benefits can also include statefunded retirement systems, debt financing held by the state on behalf of the university, provision of sovereign immunity to faculty physicians that dramatically reduce the cost of malpractice insurance, state scholarships paid directly to students attending public universities, and similar benefits that correspond to the details of state arrangements with their public institutions. While these benefits vary greatly from public institution to public institution, all of them enhance the resources that public universities have in their competition with each other and with their private counterparts for high-quality students and research. We have not yet fully explored the close relationship between institutional resources and the competition for federal research funding, but it appears likely that the substantial funds available to private and public universities as reflected in their adjusted total endowment-equivalents provide a source for strong support in this competition. We use the adjusted figure to estimate the potential institutional resources available to the university for supporting all forms of Endowment-Equivalent Total Endowment-Equivalent Adjusted for Student FTE Enrollment Universities with More Than $20 Million in Federal Research in Rank Order quality competition, including research, once it has covered its basic teaching costs. The plot of public and private university adjusted total endowment-equivalent against federal research expenditures shows a strong linear relationship. In this case, the adjusted total endowment appears to explain about 60% of the variance in federal research performance for both public and private institutions. Of course, these highly competitive institutions use their disposable income to support the acquisition of quality students and other university priorities. Nonetheless, we believe this relationship reflected in the r-square of about 0.60 indicates that the substantial resources reflected in these data explain a significant part of the success of the top research universities in the competition for federal research dollars. In this calculation, we do not include John Hopkins and Harvard because they are extreme outliers on federal research and total endowment-equivalent, respectively. Their inclusion in this analysis distorts the results and reduces the private institution r-square to 0.27. Another way to view this relationship is to look at the relationship of federal research to adjusted total endowment-equivalent. We calculated the amount of federal research expenditures per $1,000 in adjusted total endowment-equivalent for each of the 288 institutions in our sample. We then grouped the institutions into four bands based on their level of federal research in 1999. Within each band, we calculated the median amount of federal research expenditures per $1,000 for private and public universities separately. The Top American Research Universities In the group of universities with more than $20 million in federal research expenditures, public and private institutions not only have similar expenditures per $1,000 but also appear to have significantly more adjusted total endowment-equivalent resources relative to their research volume than do their less researchintensive counterparts. As we showed in last year’s report, this group of institutions at the very highest level of performance is in a category of its own. The federal research expenditures per $1,000 for private universities, in particular, demonstrate the substantial differences between this group of top competitive research universities and the other private institutions. Adjusted Total Endowment-Equivalent and Federal Research Universities with More Than $20 Million in Federal Research (excluding Harvard and Johns Hopkins) Page 22 Federal Research per $1000 Adjusted Total Endowment-Equivalent Median of Research Group by Control Mean Adjusted Total Endowment-Equivalent by Performance Score and Control Universities Over $20 Million in Federal Research Page 23 The more than $20 million private institutions’ median federal research expenditures per adjusted total endowment-equivalent is nearly four times as large as that of their closest competitive group (those with between $5 and $20 million). In contrast, the top public universities’ median federal research expenditures per $1,000 is less than two times as great as the second band of publics. Instead, the big break point for public institutions occurs at the bottom of the scale, where the median federal research expenditure per $1,000 of the $1 to $5 million publics is nearly eight times as large as the median for those public universities with less than $1 million in federal research expenditures. These relationships do not tell us how universities spend their money, but they give a sense of the resources available to institutions at the different levels of research intensity. A detailed set of case studies would allow us to understand the different ways universities allocate their funds in support of research, instruction, and other university priorities. We also categorized the research universities in our over-$20-million group by their performance scores in The Top American Research University’s taxonomy (2001). This view of the data helps us understand how the resources identified here relate to the total success of the top research universities in all the areas included in our reports. We assigned a score of 1 for every measure the institution had ranked in the top 25 by control (public and private ranked separately) and a score of 0.5 for every measure the institution had ranked from 26 to 50. Universities can range from a high score of 9 (all top 25 rankings) to a low of zero (no rankings in the top 50). The chart included here clearly shows that the universities in the group with the highest performance on our measures also enjoyed, by far, the highest mean adjusted total endowment-equivalents. Reinforcing our earlier examination by rank order, in nearly every performance category, public universities have higher mean adjusted endowment-equivalents than their private counterparts. In short, money matters. Public universities probably have as much of it to spend subsidizing the cost of high quality as private universities do, and most public institutions have stronger resource bases of total endowment-equivalent than their private counterparts. Public institutions with high total endowment-equivalents and high performance in the quality elements defined by our reports exist under every governance type. For all universities, public or private, money matters, but public universities benefit greatly by their organization as state-supported entities. Within public universities as a group, the amount of money available to support quality is likely to be much more important than the specific details of state governance organization. Endowment-Equivalent Some References on University Organization and Finance The search for an effective and stable organizational model for state systems of higher education has a long history. The simple cataloging of the various state models alone accounts for a significant amount of effort, mostly sponsored by organizations focused on higher education such as the Carnegie Foundation, the Association of Governing Boards, and the Education Commission of the States. One of the earliest efforts to address the issue of higher education organization is in Robert J. Leonard’s The Coordination of State Institutions for Higher Education Through Supplemental Curricular Boards (Berkeley: University of California, 1923), which, although narrow in scope because it focuses on only three states, nonetheless raises many of the issues that continue to drive organizational change today. More comprehensive early treatments came a decade later, in 1933 and 1934, when The Carnegie Foundation for the Advancement of Teaching helped sponsor Fred J. Kelly and John H. McNeely’s The State and Higher Education: Phases of Their Relationship (New York, 1933, in cooperation with The US Office of Education) and Edward C. Elliott and M.M. Chambers’ Charters and Basic Laws of Selected American Universities and Colleges (New York, 1934, in cooperation with Purdue University). The State and Higher Education offered a comprehensive review of college and university organization in 10 selected states with charts outlining the composition of boards and their functions and relationships along with other information on the missions of institutions including a chapter on “The Trend toward Unified Control.” Charters and Basic Laws gives a succinct summary of the charters and powers of 51 universities, over half of which are private. All of the themes that inform subsequent studies of this topic of university organization appear in these pre-World War II publications – further evidence of the persistence of the dilemmas faced by public university organizations and the difficulty of arriving at satisfactory organizational paradigms. Over the years, a significant literature on these topics emerged, responding in part to the endless changes and modifications in university governance and the characteristics of state university organization. For an interesting account of the process by which “colleges” became “universities,” see Christopher C. Morphew’s article, “‘A Rose by Any Other Name’: Which Colleges Became Universities,” The Review of Higher Education (25:2, 2002) 207-223. The renewed The Top American Research Universities interest in the topic of organization of state systems that marked the 1960s is visible in a comprehensive review of State Boards Responsible for Higher Education by S.V. Martorana and Ernest V. Hollis (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare, 1960). This state-by-state analysis with organizational diagrams and a variety of other analytical and descriptive information outlines the functions, powers, and responsibilities of the various units within these organizations. A slightly later view revisits these questions in a series of essays edited by W. John Minter, Campus and Capitol: Higher Education and the State (Boulder, Colorado: Western Interstate Commission for Higher Education, 1966). Of particular interest for our purposes are three essays on state higher education coordination and the excellent annotated bibliographies that accompany them: Samuel B. Gould, “The University and State Government,” pp. 2-15; Daniel G. Aldrich, Jr., “Maintaining Institutional Identity and Autonomy in Coordinated Systems,” pp. 16-24; Lyman A. Glenny, “Politics and Current Patterns in Coordinating Higher Education,” pp. 26-46; and the annotated bibliographies on pp. 121-147. The 1971 report on The Multicampus University: A Study of Academic Governance sponsored by The Carnegie Commission on Higher Education by Eugene C. Lee and Frank M. Bowen (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1971) provides another effective update on the evolution of university systems and once again illustrates the continuity of issues and the contextual nature of university organization. The authors offer this conclusion that sounds as current to us today as it must have in 1971 (pp.421-422): “The organization of higher education will not determine the place or the future of the university in society. Whether a state has a single-board system or single-campus institutions; whether it has a strong coordinating agency or a multicampus system...; or whether it has some combination of these—none of these factors will in and of itself solve the problems of higher education in the 1970s. [. . .] None of the alternative patterns of organization is better or worse in abstract. They take shape and can be evaluated only in terms of the environment within which they are set. Particular sets of political and social circumstances may dictate a pattern of organization which could not survive in a different context.” Page 24 Indeed, the same authors have this to say in their introduction to an excellent volume of essays published in 1999 (Gerald H. Gaither, ed., The Multicampus System: Perspectives on Practice and Prospects, Sterling, Virginia: Stylus Publishing, 1999, p. x): “The world is a different place than it was thirty years ago. But have multicampus systems changed as much as the world around them? Plus ça change, plus c’est la même chose. As significant as are the changes discussed in the essays, much remains the same.” Robert O. Berdahl, in “A View from the Bridge: Higher Education at the Macro-Management Level,” The Review of Higher Education (2000, 24:1) 103-112, a review of Gaither (ed.), The Multicampus System (1999), and in Richard Richardson, Kathy Bracco, Patrick Callan, and Joni Finney, Designing State Higher Education Systems for a New Century (Phoenix, AZ: American Council on Education/Oryx Press, 1999), offers an insightful view of these issues, drawing on the perspective of 30 years of involvement in this conversation as reflected in his earlier much-cited work Statewide Coordination of Higher Education (Washington, DC: American Council on Education, 1971). Reflecting the continuity of issues and concerns that define the organizational efforts of states on behalf of public higher education as viewed from the mid 1980s, John D. Millett’s Conflict in Higher Education: State Government Coordination Versus Institutional Independence (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1984) provides a useful historical view and an in-depth analysis of 25 states categorized by the author’s typology of higher education governance systems. In the late 1990s, D. Bruce Johnstone revisited this discussion based on his many contributions to our understanding of system operations and university finance in an excellent essay on “Management and Leadership Challenges of Multicampus Systems,” in the Gaither volume mentioned above. In 1995 Richard Novak compiled an annotated bibliography that provides a good overview of the literature in Statewide Governance, Coordination, and Trusteeship in Public Higher Education: An Annotated Bibliography (Washington, DC: Association of Governing Boards of Universities and Colleges [AGB], 1995). Indeed, the AGB’s commitment to this topic is understandably keen, and the association has sponsored a number of publications that explore the controversies and conversation about the best way to organize and manage public universities. For examples of this literature, see the collection of articles from the AGB-sponsored magazine Trusteeship that appears in Page 25 Trusteeship Portfolios, Governance of Public Higher Education (Washington, DC: AGB, 1999), many of which speak to either organizational issues directly or to the difficulties of managing universities within existing organizational models. This follows on the AGB’s publication Bridging the Gap: Between State Government and Public Higher Education (Washington, DC: AGB, 1998), a call to action on various issues of governance that touches on questions of organization and the distribution of responsibility and authority. Another useful study appeared in 1998 sponsored by The National Center for Public Policy and Higher Education (Richard C. Richardson, Jr., et al., Higher Education Governance: Balancing Institutional and Market Influences (San Jose, California, November 1998) that used a seven-state analysis to illustrate a new analytic model. In rejecting the classic definitions of state organization (consolidated governing boards, coordinating governing boards, and planning boards), the authors wrote “...these three designations, despite their earlier usefulness, are now insufficient for examining the relationships between public policy and state systems that overarch individual institutions”(p. 5). They propose instead a taxonomy using segmented, unified, and federal as the appropriate descriptors and focus on the policy issues that states address when they decide on governance structure, educational mission, institutional capacity, and work processes. Among the agencies concerned with these issues, exceptionally detailed and current information on public higher education organization appears through the work of the Education Commission of the States [ECS]. In addition to the useful paper by Aims C. McGinness, “Governance and Coordination: Definitions and Distinctions” (Denver: ECS Policy Brief, December 2001, accessed 2002 at [http://www.ecs.org/clearinghouse/31/62/3162.htm]), that reinforces the categorization of governing systems used by many observers and draws on the work of Clark Kerr and Marian Gade in The Guardians: Boards of Trustees of American Colleges and Universities: What Do They Do and How Well Do They Do It? (Washington, D.C.: AGB, 1989), the AGB publishes a comprehensive database on postsecondary governance structures on its web site. The data available there includes “A report containing all information available in the Postsecondary Governance Structures Database for a single state,” “Information on individual topics from all 50 states, where available,” and the opportunity to “Select one or more states and specific comparative information to be displayed in a single online report” ECS Tools & Resources: Postsecondary Governance Structures Database (Denver: ECS, accessed 2002 at [http: //www.ecs.org/ clearing- References house/31/02/3102.htm]). Aims C. McGinness also has an interesting presentation of organizational diagrams in “Models of Postsecondary Education Coordination and Governance in the States” (Denver: ECS, accessed 2002 at [http://www.ecs.org/clearinghouse/ 34/23/3423.htm]). J. Fredericks Volkwein demonstrates that “Changes in Quality among Public Universities” is more a function of their resources than a function of their state’s regulatory system in his article in the Journal of Higher Education (60:2, 1989, 136-151) Finally, for those interested in the long history and evolution of university organization, The Academic Corporation: A History of College and University Governing Boards by Edwin D. Duryea (New York: Falmer Press, 2000) offers a review that begins with “Medieval Origins.” This book primarily addresses the powers and legal status of universities private and public and has a thorough discussion of the various significant court cases relevant to this concern. The author looked at the founding documents of 26 private institutions and those of the public universities in 22 states. In addition, there is a very useful bibliography of relevant court cases. These represent but a sampling of the extensive literature on university governance. While our focus here is on organization, the materials on other topics related to decision making, faculty governance, and other such issues is even more extensive. The topic of university money, in all its forms, has a large and fascinating academic literature. Economists, education researchers, and many others have explored the topic of university finance from many different directions. Because of the many difficulties of using university-supplied economic data, most of the studies deal with subsets of the academic finance universe. For a quick introduction to the problems of identifying university costs, the report Explaining College Costs: NACUBO’s Methodology For Identifying The Costs of Delivering Undergraduate Education (Washington, DC: National Association of College and University Business Officers, 2002 accessed on-line July 2002 at [http://www.nacubo.org/ public_policy/cost_of_college/final_report.pdf ]) provides a good discussion on accounting issues and difficulties of estimating the costs of undergraduate education. It also provides some estimates of cost ranges using its methodology that proved helpful in our work here. Our calculations on endowment payout follow the methodology in Moody’s Investors Service, “Moody’s Introduces New Concepts to Measure Operating Performance and Leverage” (Special Comment Report, No. 41612) (New York, 1999). The Top American Research Universities Exceptionally creative work on the issue of instructional costs, pricing, and tuition discounting have come from the Williams Center project mentioned various times in the text. The papers produced on these topics appear on the The Williams Project on the Economics of Higher Education web site at [http://www.williams.edu/Mellon/project.html] and accessed in July 2002. Of particular interest is the paper on “Saving, Wealth, Performance, and Revenues in US Colleges and Universities” by Gordon C. Winston, Jared C. Carbone, and Laurie C. Hurshman (Williamstown, MA: The Williams Project, 2001), although the entire series of papers on the site are required reading for those interested in the operation of college and university finance. For our purposes in this paper, we have drawn heavily on the framework developed by Winston and colleagues for understanding the institutional competition for high-quality students and applied a similar approach to our understanding of research university competition for research faculty and their grants and contracts. In both cases, the university subsidizes the competition. For students, the mechanism involves tuition discounting and high-cost undergraduate programs and service; for research, the mechanism involves market-competitive salaries and benefits for scarce research-competent faculty and subsidies for the unreimbursed cost of their national research competition for grants, contracts, foundation support, and publication success. Also helpful in formulating this paper is the article mentioned above by Ralph M. Bradburd and Duncan P. Mann, “Wealth in Higher Education Institutions,” Journal of Higher Education (64,1993; 472-493) and available on-line through JSTOR. Of considerable utility in this conversation is Irwin Feller’s article on “The Determinants of Research Competitiveness Among Universities” in Albert H. Teich, ed., Competitiveness in Academic Research (Washington, DC: American Association for the Advancement of Science, 1996, pp. 35-72), where he clearly outlines the importance of institutional and other subsidies that pay for the costs of this competition. Sheila Slaughter and Larry L. Leslie in Academic Capitalism (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1997) offer a strong discussion of the impact of externally driven research competition on the internal academic structure and behavior of universities. The focus on faculty incentives and competition also has a long tradition. See, for example, the following two articles that illustrate the clear relationship between research and reward at the individual faculty level. James F. Ragan, Jr., John T. Warren, and Bernt Bratsberg focus on the microcosm of the economics Page 26 department in their “How Similar are Pay Structures in `Similar’ Departments of Economics?” Economics of Education Review (18:1999, 347-360) and demonstrate that high- quality research publication returns high rewards to faculty to compete successfully, further supporting the impact of national guild quality assessment on individual campus faculty and the rewards provided for their research work. James S. Fairweather’s “Myths and Realities of Academic Labor Markets,” in The Economics of Education Review (14:1995, 179-192), looks at the whole of the faculty marketplace and finds that while there is some segmentation of the market by institution type, every institution seeks out researchcapable faculty and the price for research talent is nationally determined. The topic of university revenue and expenditures and institutional finance is an endlessly fascinating and frustrating topic. See, for an example, Daniel T. Layzell’s Budgeting for Higher Education at the State Level: Enigma, Paradox, and Ritual (Washington, DC: George Washington University, 1990), D. Kent Halstead’s Higher Education Revenues and Expenditures: A Study of Institutional Costs (Washington, DC: Research Associates of Washington, 1991), and especially the more recent review of the state of the conversation in D. Bruce Johnstone, “Patterns of Finance: Revolution, Evolution, or More of the Same?” The Review of Higher Education. (21:1998, 245-255) Page 27 accessed on-line July 2002 at [http://www.press.jhu.edu/ journals/review_of_higher_education/v021/21.3johnstone.html]. The articles in Patrick M. Callan, et al., eds. Public and Private Financing of Higher Education: Shaping Public Policy for the Future (Phoenix: Oryx Press, 1997) speak to the complex array of financial resources supporting higher education and make some predictions about the future. An interesting accounting and risk analysis perspective on private university resources is in Ronald E. Salluzzo, Frederic J. Prager, et al., Ratio Analysis in Higher Education. Measuring Past Performance to Chart Future Direction (4th ed., n.p., KPMG, LLP and Prager, McCarthy Sealy, LLC, 1999). Finally, the federal government provides data on institution resources in Financial Statistics of Institutions of Higher Education; Current Funds, Revenues and Expenditures (Washington, DC: National Center for Educational Statistics, various dates), but these data are not easily used for the purposes of the kind of discussion presented here. Based on the IPEDS data collection system, the data collection and reporting system create some problems of interpretation, completeness, and consistency that render their usefulness for some purposes problematical. TheCenter staff is developing a discussion paper that will address these technical concerns, scheduled for publication in late Fall 2002. References Appendix: Endowment-Equivalent Data and Calculations Calculations The following table lists each of the research universities used in our calculation and analysis of endowment-equivalent resources (see Cost, Complexity, Regulation, and Money, pp. 20-22). These 119 institutions (39 private and 80 public) include those with more than $20 million in federal research expenditures in fiscal year 1999, and exclude stand-alone medical schools and any institutions that did not have all five key elements for this study—student enrollment, endowment assets, annual giving, state appropriations, and tuition and fees. The Total Endowment-Equivalent is the sum of these four variables, with the latter three converted to a comparable endowment-equivalent (i.e., assuming a 4.5% payout rate, we divide each figure by .045): Endowment Assets Market Value is obtained from the 1999 NACUBO Endowment Study, with adjustments made for single-campus institutions that report as a system or multi-campus university (see Data Notes for further details on adjustments, p. 163). Annual Giving data are obtained from the Council for Aid to Education’s 1999 Voluntary Support of Education Survey, with adjustments if necessary. The Top American Research Universities State Appropriations data are from the IPEDS 1999 Finance Survey (Form F-1, Line A043, for public universities; Form F-2, Line A041, for privates). Gross Tuition and Fees data are from the IPEDS 1999 Finance Survey (Form F-1, Line C2d, for public universities; Form F-2, Line A01_1 and AA08, for privates). The Adjustment for Student Enrollment is based on Fall 1999 Student Headcount data reported in IPEDS Fall Enrollment Study (Form EF-1). We use the conventional formula for converting to an FTE Headcount—three part-time students equal one fulltime student. We then multiply the FTE headcount by the following estimated baseline costs of education per level: $7,000 per undergraduate FTE headcount $8,750 per graduate FTE headcount $20,000 per professional FTE headcount The Adjusted Total Endowment-Equivalent is equal to the Total Endowment-Equivalent minus the Adjustment for Student Enrollment. Page 28 Endowment-Equivalent Components and Size Adjustment for Selected Over $20 Million Universities* Control Private Public Private Private Public Public Private Private Private Public Public Private Private Private Private Private Private Public Public Public Private Public Private Private Public Public Private Public Private Private Public Public Public Public Public Public Public Public Private Public Public Public Public Public Public Public Private Private Public Private Institution (In descending order of Adjusted Total Endowment-Equivalent) Harvard University University of Michigan - Ann Arbor Stanford University University of Pennsylvania University of Minnesota - Twin Cities University of California - Los Angeles Columbia University Yale University New York University University of California - Berkeley University of Wisconsin - Madison Massachusetts Institute of Technology University of Southern California Cornell University Princeton University Emory University Duke University Texas A&M University Ohio State University - Columbus University of Washington - Seattle Northwestern University University of North Carolina - Chapel Hill Boston University Johns Hopkins University University of Florida Pennsylvania State University - University Park University of Chicago Michigan State University Washington University in St. Louis Vanderbilt University University of California - Davis University of Georgia University of Illinois - Urbana-Champaign Purdue University - West Lafayette North Carolina State University University of Virginia University of Arizona University of California - San Diego University of Notre Dame University of Texas - Austin University of Maryland - College Park University of Pittsburgh - Pittsburgh Indiana University - Bloomington University of Nebraska - Lincoln Georgia Institute of Technology University of Kentucky Dartmouth College University of Miami University of Iowa George Washington University Page 29 1999 Endowment Assets Market Value 1999 EndowmentEquivalent Annual Giving 1999 EndowmentEquivalent State Appropriation 1999 EndowmentEquivalent Tuition & Fees 1999 Total EndowmentEquivalent Adjustment for 1999 Student Enrollment 1999 Adjusted Total EndowmentEquivalent 14,255,996 2,424,588 6,005,211 3,281,342 1,509,769 1,103,038 3,636,621 7,197,900 1,035,900 1,654,557 909,834 4,287,701 1,589,833 2,869,103 6,469,200 4,475,755 1,678,728 3,596,759 1,086,350 745,217 2,634,850 925,746 652,161 1,520,793 601,813 633,748 2,762,686 265,238 3,761,686 1,831,766 300,828 334,534 522,607 1,222,411 275,532 1,398,068 272,950 200,552 1,984,256 1,355,016 314,183 854,840 400,000 429,991 948,600 327,644 1,710,585 428,571 476,800 673,589 10,037,156 3,775,844 7,102,000 6,001,356 3,599,244 4,626,756 6,321,933 4,987,622 2,845,422 4,094,022 5,452,933 4,631,933 4,817,422 7,585,756 3,535,111 5,197,778 7,355,378 2,746,222 3,409,711 4,683,222 3,212,222 3,295,778 1,630,556 4,599,400 3,008,644 2,492,467 2,681,400 2,314,133 2,541,489 4,292,956 1,182,867 945,200 2,344,000 1,821,422 1,666,644 2,937,422 1,707,533 2,549,689 2,522,822 2,954,222 1,117,978 1,457,200 1,771,533 3,444,444 1,837,822 1,167,556 2,375,400 1,905,244 1,811,378 978,200 7,330,982 817,600 11,804,626 11,094,156 82,267 121,956 8,775,800 8,106,423 3,946,789 8,372,507 8,534,762 6,361,022 8,497,156 310,444 10,920,000 4,849,373 7,625,572 7,714,800 8,938,384 6,652,621 5,579,954 7,454,916 3,032,980 6,979,589 5,195,489 5,676,625 6,071,824 3,515,667 4,535,531 4,109,991 4,182,134 6,189,243 354,363 5,709,796 - 11,018,356 10,187,931 6,429,622 10,423,533 5,192,034 5,100,067 8,986,467 5,042,556 16,566,289 5,199,800 5,398,922 6,074,244 11,713,222 1,692,052 3,336,511 4,750,111 5,613,733 4,218,896 6,610,183 5,141,178 8,092,400 2,453,333 12,928,870 5,953,444 2,813,356 7,432,956 6,026,163 5,268,334 4,559,444 4,482,680 2,969,578 2,545,197 4,315,938 4,766,477 1,765,839 3,633,056 3,352,310 2,462,267 4,502,689 4,906,188 3,998,828 5,176,468 5,219,659 1,609,964 1,493,082 2,220,823 3,048,549 5,893,579 2,732,211 7,088,455 35,311,507 23,719,345 19,536,833 20,523,831 22,105,674 21,924,016 19,027,288 17,228,078 20,569,567 19,724,179 19,868,112 14,993,879 18,120,477 16,093,700 13,340,822 14,423,644 14,647,839 18,934,384 19,641,006 16,930,639 13,939,472 15,172,013 15,211,586 12,384,082 17,343,813 15,408,544 11,470,249 15,473,278 10,862,619 10,607,402 12,168,072 12,763,314 13,835,166 13,390,265 11,162,932 11,001,526 12,312,382 10,407,996 9,009,767 14,892,052 11,502,814 11,004,175 11,926,723 9,594,390 8,461,639 9,905,265 7,134,534 8,581,757 10,730,184 8,740,244 4,225,829 6,550,455 2,771,492 3,935,464 6,317,631 6,381,320 3,833,199 2,234,412 5,956,817 5,179,608 6,554,848 1,784,828 4,911,713 3,687,918 1,058,444 2,146,384 2,386,840 6,816,145 7,656,874 5,667,350 2,925,031 4,214,823 4,688,758 2,222,115 7,257,706 6,104,893 2,182,466 6,459,180 2,112,252 1,945,782 4,190,435 4,914,913 6,146,249 5,991,567 3,800,595 3,677,228 5,093,684 3,250,481 1,871,367 7,825,047 4,648,564 4,194,428 5,521,501 3,224,713 2,173,877 3,625,435 933,974 2,562,533 4,798,362 3,124,712 31,085,679 17,168,890 16,765,341 16,588,367 15,788,043 15,542,696 15,194,089 14,993,666 14,612,750 14,544,571 13,313,265 13,209,051 13,208,765 12,405,782 12,282,379 12,277,260 12,260,999 12,118,238 11,984,132 11,263,289 11,014,441 10,957,189 10,522,828 10,161,967 10,086,107 9,303,652 9,287,782 9,014,098 8,750,367 8,661,620 7,977,637 7,848,401 7,688,917 7,398,698 7,362,337 7,324,297 7,218,698 7,157,516 7,138,400 7,067,005 6,854,250 6,809,747 6,405,222 6,369,678 6,287,762 6,279,830 6,200,561 6,019,224 5,931,823 5,615,533 Appendix Endowment-Equivalent Components and Size Adjustment for Selected Over $20 Million Universities* (cont.) Control (In descending order of Adjusted Total Endowment-Equivalent) 1999 Endowment Assets Market Value Public Public Public Private Private Public Private Public Public Public Private Public Private Private Public Public Public Public Public Public Public Private Public Private Public Private Private Private Public Public Public Public Public Public Public Public Public Public Private Public Public Public Private Public Public Public Public Public Public Private Iowa State University Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University Temple University Brown University Rice University University of Utah Syracuse University University of Illinois - Chicago University of Connecticut - Storrs University of Cincinnati - Cincinnati Georgetown University University at Buffalo California Institute of Technology Case Western Reserve University University of Missouri - Columbia University of Delaware Indiana University-Purdue University - Indianapolis Arizona State University - Tempe University of Massachusetts - Amherst Wayne State University University of California - Irvine University of Rochester Washington State University - Pullman Northeastern University University of Tennessee - Knoxville Tufts University Carnegie Mellon University Tulane University Clemson University University of South Florida University of South Carolina - Columbia University of Alabama - Birmingham University at Stony Brook University of Kansas - Lawrence Auburn University - Auburn West Virginia University Florida State University University of Hawaii - Manoa Wake Forest University Louisiana State University - Baton Rouge Oregon State University Oklahoma State University - Stillwater Saint Louis University - St. Louis University of Colorado - Boulder University of California - Santa Barbara Texas Tech University Virginia Commonwealth University University of New Mexico - Albuquerque Mississippi State University Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute 266,348 340,244 141,527 1,181,514 2,936,622 269,430 641,466 106,154 100,019 898,976 684,193 438,002 1,333,229 1,434,200 350,319 777,349 350,000 183,440 60,579 146,275 100,276 1,119,027 421,402 396,205 151,240 464,107 719,320 548,305 214,566 202,784 253,775 204,680 22,383 613,338 233,049 254,576 247,471 146,459 857,938 176,925 241,973 156,074 907,822 195,585 100,276 197,532 200,793 193,377 160,399 516,238 Institution The Top American Research Universities 1999 EndowmentEquivalent Annual Giving 1999 EndowmentEquivalent State Appropriation 1999 EndowmentEquivalent Tuition & Fees 1999 Total EndowmentEquivalent Adjustment for 1999 Student Enrollment 1999 Adjusted Total EndowmentEquivalent 1,099,778 1,586,067 986,333 1,668,667 1,741,378 2,789,867 748,511 781,333 523,356 905,889 1,823,956 372,422 3,068,689 1,674,267 897,133 891,267 1,594,400 1,035,778 428,178 760,444 1,078,778 1,073,800 916,444 628,178 947,289 1,167,889 906,978 1,337,778 740,311 437,644 1,120,822 846,556 257,400 1,438,600 842,467 624,178 1,211,111 298,911 1,047,978 855,556 910,178 779,733 670,267 1,152,733 431,889 1,344,178 611,267 562,356 585,000 810,356 5,834,442 4,512,065 3,544,156 1,667 4,015,022 49,720 5,867,337 4,737,372 3,839,337 5,749,837 117,556 4,114,272 1,996,371 4,091,212 5,717,422 4,462,400 5,143,921 3,929,422 32,156 3,806,648 4,885,746 116,111 26,733 3,614,423 5,944,343 3,560,904 3,694,341 4,478,928 2,735,259 3,733,182 3,948,834 4,724,683 3,874,512 35,156 4,622,370 2,575,223 3,642,316 1,658,484 3,516,889 2,945,039 3,264,124 4,084,286 3,000,404 19,622 2,282,133 3,431,155 5,017,133 3,804,467 1,362,911 1,602,733 6,573,796 2,406,764 2,460,946 3,259,991 5,084,778 2,224,756 752,400 3,209,244 3,024,866 4,034,428 2,319,584 3,804,333 3,055,356 2,329,759 2,405,822 3,494,844 2,248,787 6,349,546 2,280,498 4,280,619 3,776,335 4,261,622 1,925,353 1,468,667 2,591,833 1,313,618 1,695,649 2,426,281 2,114,228 2,114,047 1,999,718 1,508,100 2,557,988 2,278,580 1,749,047 1,355,365 3,373,534 4,047,063 2,028,800 2,024,881 2,040,229 1,221,062 1,287,907 2,503,622 9,482,700 9,869,531 9,689,149 6,656,314 6,040,911 8,677,052 8,013,493 9,161,588 7,821,692 8,904,193 7,592,926 8,785,017 5,154,318 6,435,267 8,386,590 7,699,415 8,355,196 10,740,973 8,006,512 8,380,400 7,514,298 5,719,827 7,393,281 7,373,929 8,264,773 6,028,726 5,402,633 6,174,438 6,494,653 8,053,439 7,527,334 6,059,194 6,454,360 7,213,478 6,922,925 6,941,635 8,182,983 5,827,982 4,499,060 7,933,431 5,476,420 5,933,488 4,951,623 7,053,865 6,077,854 6,511,630 6,116,413 6,061,080 5,033,710 3,849,838 3,893,219 4,287,326 4,286,664 1,301,883 707,455 3,366,438 2,797,378 4,073,425 2,771,511 3,891,731 2,660,972 3,872,596 332,033 1,681,988 3,653,738 2,968,426 3,628,765 6,029,743 3,503,666 3,963,536 3,115,880 1,348,488 3,094,051 3,080,704 4,011,225 1,923,293 1,311,896 2,097,321 2,480,236 4,069,261 3,552,428 2,234,229 2,792,290 3,660,577 3,401,334 3,502,438 4,805,880 2,460,014 1,202,247 4,827,557 2,414,946 2,879,380 1,951,319 4,077,690 3,128,705 3,670,800 3,294,524 3,317,046 2,291,251 1,118,000 5,589,481 5,582,205 5,402,485 5,354,431 5,333,456 5,310,614 5,216,115 5,088,163 5,050,181 5,012,462 4,931,954 4,912,421 4,822,285 4,753,279 4,732,852 4,730,989 4,726,431 4,711,231 4,502,846 4,416,864 4,398,419 4,371,339 4,299,230 4,293,225 4,253,548 4,105,433 4,090,737 4,077,117 4,014,417 3,984,177 3,974,906 3,824,965 3,662,070 3,552,901 3,521,592 3,439,197 3,377,103 3,367,968 3,296,813 3,105,874 3,061,474 3,054,107 3,000,304 2,976,175 2,949,149 2,840,830 2,821,889 2,744,033 2,742,459 2,731,838 Page 30 TheCenter Advisory Board TheCenter Staff Arthur M. Cohen John V. Lombardi Professor, Higher Education and Work Director, ERIC Clearinghouse for Community Colleges University of California, Los Angeles Co-Editor, TheCenter Chancellor, University of Massachusetts Amherst Larry Goldstein Elizabeth D. Capaldi President, Campus Strategies Fellow, SCT Senior Fellow, NACUBO Co-Editor, TheCenter Provost, University at Buffalo Gerardo M. Gonzalez Research Director, TheCenter University of Florida University Dean for the School of Education Indiana University D. Bruce Johnstone Professor, Department of Educational Leadership and Policy Director, Learning Productivity Network Director, International Comparative Higher Education Finance and Accessibility Project University at Buffalo Roger Kaufman Professor and Director, Office for Needs Assessment and Planning Associate Director, Learning Systems Institute Florida State University Gordon C. Winston Orrin Sage Professor of Political Economy Co-Director, Mellon Project Williams College The Top American Research Universities Diane D. Craig Lynne N. Collis Administrative Services, TheCenter University of Florida Denise S. Gater Research Associate, TheCenter Associate Director, Office of Institutional Research University of Florida Ralph E. Horky Courtesy Research Associate, TheCenter University of Florida Anney B. Doucette Student Assistant, TheCenter University of Florida Page 31